Skip to main content

Full text of "Principles of political geography"

See other formats


OLITICAL 


OGRAPH 


HS*rf\ 


;:    ''    * 


ONE  WORLD 
DIVIDED 


ALASKA 


1956 


GREENLAND 


ARd 


s* 


*•> 


XEIAND  J 


V  * 


,?> 


• 


NETH^WEST, 

tux?." 
FRANCE  v^Sn 


PORTUGAL 


/ 

/      SPAIN 
/ 


"v..      ^>— a 


<J 


MOROCCO 


3 


/ 

(tunisia  I 


ALGERIA 


*m 


Neutralist  Nations  and  Nations  Not  Participating  in  Western  Defense  Pacts 


THE  NORTHERN 
HEMISPHERE 


v 


-•^•RUMANIA1 

i  auiv 


i 


-X 


^ 


IRAQ 


..-<* 


*ranean      Sea 


bya? 


iebanonE£^_aw,w._.<V! 


Tha  "West":  NATO  ond  Baghdad  Pact  Nations 


U.S.S.R.,  China,  and  Satellite  Nations 


UNIVERSITY 

OF  FLORIDA 

LIBRARIES 

m 

\im/ 

COLLEGE  LIBRARY 

• 

PRINCIPLES 

of 

POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 


BY 

Hans  W.  Weigert 

GEORGETOWN    UNIVERSITY 

Henry  Brodie 

DEPARTMENT    OF    STATE 

Edward  "W.  Donerty 

DEPARTMENT    OF    STATE 

John  R.  Fernstrom 

GEORGETOWN    UNIVERSITY 

Eric  Fischer 

GEORGE    WASHINGTON    UNIVERSITY 

Dudley  Kirk 

THE    POPULATION    COUNCIL,    INC. 


New  York:  APPLETON-CENTURY-CROFTS,  Inc. 


Copyright,  ©  1957,  by 
APPLETON-CENTURY-CROFTS,  INC. 

All  rights  reserved.  This  book,  or  parts 
thereof,  must  not  be  reproduced  in  any 
form  without  permission  of  the  publishers. 

653-5 
Library  of  Congress  Card  Number:  56-9859 


PRINTED    IN    THE    UNITED    STATES    OF    AMERICA 

E-92967 


Introduction 


This  study  of  political  geography  is  not  an  ordinary  textbook.  The  sub- 
ject is  both  in  the  field  of  political  science  and  of  geography,  and  being 
both  it  must  be  analytical  in  all  its  aspects;  for  the  attempt  to  show  the 
interrelationship  and  the  blending  of  political  and  geographical  factors  in 
power  relations  is  analytical  in  nature.  The  result  is  a  book  which  con- 
fronts the  reader  with  the  facts  and  problems  of  political  geography, 
stating  the  facts  and  posing  the  problems  without,  however,  attempting 
to  find  easy  answers  for  the  latter.  It  aims,  above  all,  at  making  the  reader 
realize  the  importance  and  magnitude  of  the  problems  that  arise  from  the 
interrelationship  of  political  and  geographical  factors.  The  emphasis  on 
problems  accounts  for  our  statement  that  this  volume  is  not  an  ordinary 
textbook. 

It  is  not  a  well-paved  and  easy  road  that  we  propose  to  travel  in  our 
effort  to  link  the  two  realms  of  geography  and  of  man's  political  authority 
and  organization  within  his  natural  environment.  The  view,  and  the 
review,  of  this  relationship  is  characterized  and  complicated  by  the 
dominant  fact  that  the  realm  of  political  geography  is  subject  to  constant 
change  and  fluctuation.  We  have  become  used  to  the  phrase  that  ours  is 
a  "shrinking  world."  In  no  phase  of  history  has  this  shrinking  process 
progressed  as  rapidly  as  in  our  time.  In  this  rapid  revolution  of  change, 
instability  has  become  a  main  characteristic  of  our  political  world.  The 
factor  of  instability  renders  the  task  of  exploring  the  synthesis  of  political 
activity  and  natural  environment  both  difficult  and  challenging.  The 
rapidity  with  which  the  shrinking  process  progresses  creates  a  cultural 
lag,  for  man,  in  the  words  of  Vilhjalmur  Stefansson,  "has  learned  to  change 
the  face  of  nature  but  not  to  change  his  own  mind."  We  have  been 
trained  to  interpret  the  laws  of  nature  as  they  reveal  themselves  in  our 
natural  environment,  but  with  this  knowledge  we  have  not  acquired  the 
wisdom  to  discern  the  relationship  and  the  conditioning  effects  of  natural 


vi  INTRODUCTION 

environment  and  man's  political  behavior  within  it.  The  wisdom  of  the 
Bible  still  rings  true  (St.  Luke,  XII:  54-56): 

And  He  said  also  to  the  crowds:  "When  you  see  a  cloud  rising  in  the  west, 
you  say  at  once,  'a  shower  is  coming,'  and  so  it  comes  to  pass.  And  when  you 
see  the  south  wind  blow,  you  say,  'there  will  be  a  scorching  heat,'  and  so  it 
comes  to  pass.  You  hypocrites!  You  know  how  to  judge  the  face  of  the  sky  and 
of  the  earth;  but  how  is  it  that  you  do  not  judge  this  time?" 


Aware  of  the  problems  and  difficulties  awaiting  the  student  of  political 
geography  who  is  not  afraid  of  taking  a  hard  look  at  its  realities,  the 
authors  of  this  book  found  themselves  in  full  agreement  on  one  basic  issue 
of  organization:  they  decided  in  favor  of  a  functional  rather  than  regional 
approach  to  political  geography.  Only  in  Part  3,  on  "The  Economic 
Factor  in  Political  Geography,"  did  it  appear  advisable  to  stress  re- 
gional groupings.  Mindful  of  the  uneasy  balance  of  political  power  that  is 
the  product  of  varying  geographical  and  economic  conditions,  the  au- 
thors follow  the  regional  approach  in  the  part  mentioned  to  provide  a 
useful  assessment  of  the  aggregate  economic  capabilities  characteristic 
of  certain  major  countries  and  regions. 

It  is  not  our  intention  to  present  the  reader  with  all  the  politico- 
geographical  facts  of  each  country,  or  of  all  political  groupings,  on  the 
globe.  Such  encyclopedic  enumeration  of  facts  and  figures,  available  from 
many  published  sources  and  providing  a  helpful  tool  in  our  task,  is  not 
enough  if  one  tries  to  penetrate  to  the  roots  of  the  subject.  The  func- 
tional approach,  as  we  see  it,  does  not  supply  the  reader  with  easy 
answers  to  the  manifold  problems  in  our  field.  Nor  does  it  try  to  illuminate 
each  and  every  scene  where  political  geography  has  a  legitimate  place. 
It  does,  however,  tend  to  sharpen  our  geographical  "view,"  or  what  has 
been  called  "geographical  sense,"  of  the  world's  scene.  It  undertakes  to 
forge  the  tools  with  which  the  political  geographer  applies  general  func- 
tional findings  to  whatever  political  area  he  desires  to  bring  into  focus. 


That  this  book  is  the  common  labor  of  six  authors  requires  an  explana- 
tion. The  borderlines  which  separate  our  subject  from  other  related  fields, 
as  for  instance  economic  geography  and  demography,  are  often  extremely 
thin  and  difficult  to  define.  Thus  the  student  of  political  geography  is 
often  compelled  to  step  beyond  the  narrow  confines  of  his  realm.  The 
necessity  to  deal  with  problems  requiring  specialized  skill  and  background 


INTRODUCTION  vii 

convinced  us  that  the  co-operation  between  a  number  of  authors  with 
complementary  fields  of  study  and  interest  in  the  general  area  of  political 
geography  would  result  in  a  more  definitive  and  constructive  product 
than  one  man's  labor  could  create.  On  the  other  hand,  this  book  is  not 
a  mere  symposium.  The  target  of  our  common  venture  was  a  uniform 
and  integrated  work.  The  authors  have  made  a  conscientious  effort  to 
write  their  contributions  in  close  co-ordination.  To  achieve  this  task 
it  was  essential  that  they  subscribe  to  certain  basic  principles  or  to 
what  might  be  called  a  common  philosophy  in  their  treatment  of  political 
geography.  The  reader  will  detect  this  "philosophy"  in  and  between  the 
lines  of  our  book.  It  is  essentially  a  devotion  to  objective  analysis.  It  is 
also  to  be  found  in  the  absence  of  a  negative  quality  (for  which  the 
pseudo-science  of  geopolitics  has  rightly  been  criticized),  namely  of 
partisan  politics:  the  authors  have  no  political  axes  to  grind.  That  their 
target  of  ideal  integration  has  not  always  been  reached  seems  to  be  the 
price  one  must  pay  in  the  endeavor  to  produce  teamwork.  The  critical 
reader  will  discover  easily  that  the  authors'  attempt  at  reaching  uni- 
formity in  their  presentation  has  not  been  carried  to  the  extreme,  and  that 
no  effort  was  made  to  suppress  their  individualities  and  to  harness  their 
style  and  general  approach  to  their  specific  problems.  Whether  or  not 
they  have  succeeded  in  traveling  safely  the  hazardous  path  between 
the  devil  and  the  deep  blue  sea  is  for  the  reader  to  discover. 


This  book  presents  its  material  in  three  main  parts,  following  an  in- 
troductory section  on  the  meaning  and  scope  of  political  geography.  These 
distinguish  between  the  spatial,  the  human  and  cultural,  and  the  eco- 
nomic factors  in  political  geography.  This  final  part  does  not  attempt  to  be 
a  substitute  for  a  text  in  economic  geography  but  is  limited  to  the  dis- 
cussion of  those  economic  factors  in  power  relations  the  understanding  of 
which  we  consider  essential  to  the  study  of  political  geography.  Their 
absence  from  a  book  of  this  kind  would  make  our  approach  to  political 
geography  impractical  and  unrealistic. 

In  order  to  identify  the  responsibilities  of  the  individual  authors  it 
may  be  stated  that  Mr.  Weigert  has  served  as  general  editor  with  re- 
sponsibility for  the  over-all  organization  of  the  book  and  the  integration 
of  its  various  sections,  and  that  Mr.  Fernstrom  has  undertaken  the 
cartographical  work.  In  particular,  Part  1  ( The  Spatial  Factor  in  Political 
Geography )  has  been  prepared  by  Mr.  Fischer  and  Mr.  Weigert  ( Fischer, 
pp.  26-208;  Weigert,  pp.  3-25,  209-290);  Part  2  (The  Human  and  Cultural 


viii  INTRODUCTION 

Factor  in  Political  Geography ) ,  by  Mr.  Kirk,  Mr.  Fischer,  and  Mr. 
Weigert  (Kirk,  pp.  291-341;  Kirk  and  Weigert,  pp.  342-382;  Weigert, 
pp.  383-404;  Fischer,  pp.  405-439;  Weigert,  pp.  440-445),  and  Part  3 
(The  Economic  Factor  in  Political  Geography)  by  Mr.  Brodie  and  Mr. 
Doherty  (Doherty,  pp.  449-566;  Brodie,  pp.  567-712). 

It  is  inevitable  that  in  spite  of  our  endeavor  to  avoid  when  possible  the 
discussion  of  temporary  developments,  certain  findings  and  statements  in 
this  book,  as  well  as  details  of  the  political  maps,  will  have  become  ob- 
solete by  the  time  this  book  is  published.  Therefore,  it  should  be  noted 
that  the  authors  have  considered  events  only  until  early  1956. 

Most  of  the  authors  are  associated  with  work  for  the  United  States 
Government,  and  all  of  them  have  at  some  time  been  in  public  service. 
For  this  reason  it  is  pointed  out  that  our  book  presents  the  thinking  of 
the  authors  as  private  citizens  only  and  does  not  reflect  the  views  of  the 
government  agencies  with  which  they  are,  or  have  been,  connected.  Our 
materials  are  based  on  open  sources  and  no  use  whatsoever  has  been 
made  of  classified  documents. 

The  authors  wish  to  express  their  sincere  thanks  to  Professor  Kirtley  F. 
Mather,  who,  as  Editor  of  the  Century  Earth  Science  Series,  guided  us 
with  patience  and  wisdom;  to  Mrs.  Claire  Brogan,  who  bore  the  main 
burden  of  typing  and  retyping  our  manuscript;  to  Mrs.  Mary  Dyer,  who 
helped  us  greatly  in  editing  some  of  our  chapters;  to  Richard  P.  Joyce 
who  contributed  generously  in  the  preparation  of  the  index  and  to  Mrs. 
Joyce  T.  Lutz  who  typed  the  index;  last  but  not  least,  we  feel  obligated 
to  mention  gratefully  the  long  and  (mostly)  silent  sufferings  of  our 
wives,  who  had  to  endure  the  labor  and  birth  pains  surrounding  this 
effort. 

H.W.W. 


Contents 


CHAPTER 


PAGE 

INTRODUCTION V 


PART  1 
The  Spatial  Factor  in  Political  Geography 

1  The  Meaning  and  Scope  of  Political  Geography 3 

2  Size        26 

3  Shape 58 

4  The  Nature  and  Functions  of  Boundaries 79 

5  The  Impact  of  Boundaries 110 

6  Political  Core  Areas,  Capital  Cities,  Communications     .      .      .  142 

7  Location 174 

8  The  Impact  of  Location  on  Strategy  and  Power  Politics  .      .      .  209 


PART  2 

The  Human  and  Cultural  Factor  in 
Political  Geography 

9  Population  Growth  and  Pressure 293 

10  Migrations        342 

11  The  Political  Geography  of  Languages 383 

12  Religions :  Their  Distribution  and  Role  in  Political  Geography  405 

13  Supplement:  Other  Cultural  Factors 440 

ix 


x  CONTENTS 

PART  3 
The  Economic  Factor  in  Political  Geography 

CHAPTER  PAGE 

14  The  Importance  of  Economic  Factors  in  Political  Geography     .  449 

15  The  Growing  Economic  Strength  of  the  Sino-Soviet  Bloc           .  471 

16  Japan's  Economy 519 

17  The  Economic  Capabilities  of  Western  Europe  .      .      .      .      .  531 

18  The  United  States  and  Canada 567 

19  The  Challenge  of  the  Underdeveloped  Areas 601 

20  Southwest  Asia 624 

21  South  and  Southeast  Asia 643 

22  Latin  America 665 

23  Africa:  The  Last  Stand  of  Colonialism 689 

index 713 


List  of  Maps 


PAGE 

2-  1.    Danzig-1919-1939 32 

2-  2.    Short-lived  City-states  at  the  Head  of  the  Adriatic  Sea     ...  33 

2-  3.    Portuguese  and  French  (1954)  Colonial  Holdings  in  India   .       .  35 

2-  4.    The  Ukrainian  SSR   (1955) 41 

2-  5.    Comparative  Size  of  France  (superimposed  on  Minnesota,  Iowa, 

and  Wisconsin) 42 

2-  6.    India  and  Europe  at  the  Same  Scale 43 

2-  7.  Comparative  Size  of  U.S.S.R.,  United  States,  and  Brazil  ...  44 
2-  8.    Effects  of  Projections  on  Appearance  of  Size:    Greenland  and 

South  America;  Ellesmere  Island  and  Australia 45 

2-  9.    Canada:  Population  Density  per  Square  Mile 48 

2-10.    Australia-Continental  Shelf 49 

2-11.    Encircling  Growth  of  Metropolitan  Area:   Detroit      ....  55 

3-  1.    Pakistan:  A  Non-contiguous  State  Area 59 

3-  2.    Basutoland:  An  Enclave  in  the  Union  of  South  Africa  ....  61 

3-  3.    Berlin:  An  Exclave 64 

3-  4.    British  Influence  around  the  Indian  Ocean  between  World  Wars 

I  and  II   .       .     - 68 

3-  5.    Indonesia,  an  Example  of  a  Contemporary  Circum-marine  State  .  70 

3-  6.    The  Caribbean  Sea:   An  American  Mediterranean      ....  72 

3-  7.    Portuguese  and  German  Expansion  in  Central  Africa  ....  75 

3-  8.    The  Map  as  a  Weapon  of  Geopolitics:  Czechoslovakia,  a  "Threat" 

to  Nazi  Germany 77 

4-  1.    The  Boundaries  of  Poland  since  World  War  II 82 

4-  2.    Antarctic  Claims 84 

4-  3.    Rub'al  Khali,  "The  Empty  Quarter"  of  Southern  Arabia  ...  88 

4-  4.    The  Argentine-Chilean  Boundary 91 

4-  5.    The  Minnesota-Canada  Boundary 92 

4-  6.    The  Bratislava  Bridgehead  on  the  Danube 98 

4-  7.    The  Louisiana  Extension  on  the  Mouth  of  the  Mississippi      .       .  98 

4-  8.    The  Geometrical  Line  as  Boundary:  Alaska-Siberia    ....  103 

4-  9.  Boundary  Disputes  between  States  in  the  United  States  .  .  .  106 
4-10.    Germany  Divided  (1955) 108 

5-  1.    The  Saar:   Coal  and  Steel  Industries 113 

5-  2.    The  Congo  Territory:  Exchanges  between  Belgium  and  Portugal  123 

xi 


xii  LIST  OF  MAPS 

PAGE 

5-  3.    State  Boundaries  in  the  Continental  Shelf:  Louisiana  and  Texas  125 

5-  4.    The  Sector  Principle  in  the  Arctic  Ocean 126 

5-  5.    The  United   States-Mexican   Boundary 129 

5-  6.    The  Satellite  Countries  of  Eastern  Europe 133 

5-  7.    The  Break-up  of  the  Hapsburg  Empire  after  1918     ....  139 

6-  1.    The  Shifting  Core  of  Turkey 144 

6-  2.    The  Core  Area  of  Israel 147 

6-  3.    Core  Areas  in  South  America 150 

6-  4.    Brazil:  Shift  of  Capitals 152 

6-  5.    Capitals  of  China .  154 

6-  6.    Core  Areas  of  Japan  According  to  Population  Density  per  Square 

Kilometer 155 

6-  7.    Post  Roads  of  France 159 

6-  8.    Railroad  Pattern  in  Western  Europe 160 

6-  9.    Ineffective  Rail-net  of  Czechoslovakia  at  the  Time  of  Its  Forma- 

tion       162 

6-10.    Shipping  Lanes  Radiating  from  United  Kingdom  Ports            .       .  164 

6-11.    The  St.  Lawrence  Seaway  and  the  American  Manufacturing  Belt  166 

6-12.    The  West  Coast  Area  of  the  United  States  Centered  on  California  170 

7-  1.    The  Boer  States  in  Relation  to  British  and  Portuguese  Territories  .  177 
7-  2.    The  Buffer  States  of  Iran,  Afghanistan,  and  Siam  before  the  Par- 
tition of  India 178 

7-  3.    The  Buffer  State  of  Ethiopia  before  1935 179 

7-  4.    Boundary  Conflicts  in  South  America  ........  180 

7-  5.    Bolivia  to  the  Sea  via  Brazil 181 

7-  6.    Central  Africa:  Railroad  Competition  between  Belgium,  Portugal, 

and  British  Rhodesia 186 

7-  7.    The  Palestine-Syria  Corridor 192 

8-  1.    Mackinder's  Heartland    (1904) 210 

8-  2.    Relationship  of  Heartland  and  North  America  on  the  Azimuthal 

Polar  Projection 216 

8-  3.    Marginal  Lands  to  the  West  of  the  Heartland 225 

8-  4.    Succession  of  Marginal  and  Enclosed  Seas— from  North  America 

to  the  Indian  Ocean 230 

8-  5.    The  South  China  Sea 232 

8-  6.    The  Sea  of  Japan 236 

8-  7.    The  Baltic  Arena  and  Its  String  of  Soviet  Military  Bases  .       .       .  238 

8-  8.    The  Mediterranean         240 

8-  9.  Drake  Passage  in  Relation  to  the  Panama  and  Suez  Canals  .  .  246 
8-10.  Air  Routes  and  Strategic  Bases  in  the  Arctic  Mediterranean  .  .  248 
8-11,  Sea  Routes  and  Bases  in  the  Arctic  Mediterranean  ....  252 
8-12.  The  Partition  of  Tordesillas:  The  World  Divided  ....  254 
8-13.  The  Shrinking  of  Main  Water  Bodies  in  the  Light  of  Tech- 
nological Progress 260 


LIST  OF  MAPS  xiii 

PAGE 

8-14,    The  Boundary  between  the  Eastern  and  Western  Hemispheres 

According  to  V.  Stefansson ...  264 

8-15.    Greenland  and  Iceland  between  the  Eastern  and  Western  Hemi- 
spheres     .      .             265 

8-16.    The  "American  Quarter  Sphere"            266 

8-17.    The  American  Perimeter  of  Defense:  Winter  1955     ....  274 

8-18.    The  Western  Security  System 280 

8-19.    Strategic  Railroad  Extension  in  Turkey  and  Iran 284 

8-20.    The  Columbo  Powers 287 

8-21.    Bandung  Conference,  1955 289 

9-  1.    World,  Relative  Land  Areas 294 

9-  2.    World,  Relative  Population  and  Birth  Rates 296 

9-  3.    Population  Growth,  1900-1949 315 

9-  4.    World  Regions  by  Demographic  Type 322 

9-  5.    World  Population  Growth:   Actual,   1650-1950;  and  United  Na- 
tions Medium  Estimates,  1950-1980                          323 

9-  6.    Population  Growth  in  the  World  and  Its  Major  Regions:  Actual, 

1920-1950;  and  United  Nations  Medium  Estimates,  1950-1980    .  324 

9-  7.    India:  Composition  of  Population 328 

9-  8.    Japan:  Composition  of  Population 328 

9-  9.    United  Kingdom:  Composition  of  Population 329 

9-10.    People,  Land,  and  Food  Production 333 

10-   1.     Mass   Migration   of  Ethnic   Germans   into   West   Germany   after 

World  War  II 360 

10-  2.  Net  Postwar  Overseas  Migration,  Europe  1946-1952  (in  thou- 
sands)                                  368 

10-  3.    Chinese  Settlement  in  Malaya 378 

11-  1.    Linguistic  States  of  India 386 

11-  2.    Canada:  "Les  Canadiens" 391 

11-  3.    China:  Areas  of  Languages  and  Dialects 404 

12-  1.    Distribution  of  Religions 410 

12-  2.    Distribution  of  Roman  Catholicism 416 

12-  3.  Distribution  of  (a)  Protestantism  and  other  non-Catholic  Chris- 
tian Churches;  (b)  Buddhism;  (c)  Hinduism;  (d)  Judaism           .  420 

12-  4.    Countries     with     Islamic     Majorities     and     Significant     Islamic 

Minorities 424 

12-  5.    Islamic  Countries 426 

13-  1.    World:  Daily  Newspaper  Circulation  per  100  Persons     .       .       .  442 

13-  2.    World:  Radio  Sets  per  100  Persons 444 

14-  1.    Atomic  Energy  Resources 456 

14-  2.    World:   Arable  Land 462 

14-  3.    World:  Economically  Developed  Countries 468 


xiv  LIST  OF  MAPS 

PAGE 

15-  1.    Railroads,  Resources,  and  Industrial  Concentrations  in  European 

Soviet    Union 476 

15-  2.    Railroads,    Resources,    and    Industrial   Concentrations    in    Asian 

Soviet   Union 478 

15-  3.    Railroads,  Resources,  and  Industrial  Concentrations  of  Northern 

China 498 

16-  1.    Japan:  Industrial  Areas  and  Selected  Railroads 520 

17-  1.    Railroads,  Resources,  and  Industrial  Concentrations  in  Western 

Europe 540 

18-  1.    The  Westward  Course  of  the  United  States  as  Shown  in  the  Ten- 

Year  Shift  of  the  Population  Center,  1790-1950 572 

18-  2.    Anglo- America:   Railroads,  Resources,  and  Industrial  Concentra- 
tions      574 

18-3.    Regional  Extent  of  TVA  Activity 579 

20-  1.    Middle  East  Oil  Fields  and  Pipelines 628 

21-  1.    Southeast  Asia:   Railroads,  Resources,  and  Industrial  Concentra- 

tions     652 

22-  1.    Central  America:    Resources 670 

22-  2.    South  America:  Resources 674 

23-  1.    Resources,  Railroads,  and  Political  Structure  of  Africa     .      .      .      690 


Part 


1 


THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR 
IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 


CHAPTER 


1 


The  Meaning  and  Scope  or 
Political  Geography 


POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY  AND  HUMAN  GEOGRAPHY 

Political  geography  is  a  legitimate  child  of  human  geography.  Both  deal 
with  the  interplay  of  physical  and  human  factors,  with  the  interrelation- 
ship between  earth  and  man.  Both  try  to  discover  and  explain  the  in- 
fluences of  the  physical  world  on  human  society  and  the  limitations  it  puts 
on  human  activities;  they  deal  with  diverse  manifestations  of  a  symbiosis 
of  nature  and  man. 

The  life  patterns  revealed  in  this  symbiosis  are  the  subject  matter  of 
human  geography.  Out  of  the  study  of  human  geography  evolves  a  better 
understanding  of  human  groups  within  their  natural  environment,  of 
civilizations  formed  and  grown  in  a  variety  of  environments,  and  of  the 
physical  causes  which  influenced  this  growth.1 

It  is,  perhaps,  the  roots  of  human  groups  in  their  natural  environment 
that  most  influence  their  development.  These  are,  however,  not  the  only 
formative  factors  in  human  society.  Historical  and  sociological  motiva- 
tions, as  well  as  cultural  influences,  cannot  be  discounted.  Yet  to  be 
rooted  in  a  natural  and  cultural  landscape  and  environment  is  the  essence 
of  life  to  the  individual  and  to  the  group.  The  roots  are  manifold;  so  strong 
and  interwoven  is  their  net  that  man  and  his  natural  environment  are 
inseparable.  Human  geography,  in  its  many  manifestations,  draws  its 

1  P.  W.  J.  Vidal  de  la  Blache,  Principles  of  Human  Geography  (London,  1926), 
p.  19. 

3 


4  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

inspiration  from  this  complex  symbiosis.  It  focuses  our  attention  on  man 
and  his  environment,  on  man  as  a  geographical  factor,  thus  growing 
beyond  descriptive  narrative.  Human  geography  evolves  as  a  discipline 
whose  primary  target  is  "the  study  of  human  society  in  relation  to  the 
earth  background."  2  As  such  it  ranks  alongside  of  other  social  sciences 
whose  common  purpose  is  to  study  the  structure  and  behavior  of  human 
society. 

By  this  definition  of  the  scope  of  human  geography  we  have,  by  im- 
plication, excluded  geographical  speculations  which  are  not  borne  out 
by  scientific  research.  Numerous  concepts  have  been  developed  over  the 
last  fifty  years.  These  range  from  "environmental  determinism,"  which 
postulates  a  causal  relationship  between  the  characteristics  of  the  earth 
and  the  activities  of  man,  to  modified  theories  of  "possibilism."  which 
grants  man  and  human  groups  a  number  of  possible  choices  among  the 
limits  set  and  the  opportunities  offered  by  the  physical  environment.  In  a 
philosophical  vein  and  in  lofty  language  the  concept  of  "possibilism"  was 
expressed  by  Alexis  de  Tocqueville:  3 

I  am  aware  that  many  of  my  contemporaries  maintain  that  nations  are  never 
their  own  masters  here  below,  and  that  they  necessarily  obey  some  unsurmount- 
able  and  intelligent  power,  arising  from  anterior  events,  from  their  race,  or  from 
the  soil  and  climate  of  their  country.  Such  principles  are  false  and  cowardly; 
such  principles  can  never  produce  aught  but  feeble  men  and  pusillanimous 
nations.  Providence  has  not  created  mankind  entirely  dependent  or  entirely 
free.  It  is  true  that  around  every  man  a  fatal  circle  is  traced  beyond  which  he 
cannot  pass;  but  within  the  wide  verge  of  that  circle  he  is  powerful  and  free; 
as  it  is  with  men,  so  with  communities. 

These  theories  of  determinism  and  of  possibilism,  developed  mainly  by 
geographers  in  Europe,  especially  in  Germany  and  France,  were  also 
accepted  readily  by  several  geographers  in  the  United  States.  Later  a 
healthy  reaction  occurred,  primarily  based  on  the  realization  that  al- 
though significant  changes  in  the  physical  environment  will  often  strongly 
condition  human  affairs,  a  positive  determinism  cannot  be  demonstrated 
in  a  relatively  stable  environment.  The  general  concept  commonly  ac- 
cepted today  is  "that  the  physical  character  of  the  earth  has  different 
meaning  for  different  people:  that  the  significance  to  man  of  the  physical 
environment  is  a  function  of  the  attitudes,  objectives,  and  technical  abili- 
ties of  man  himself.  With  each  change  in  any  of  the  elements  of  the 
human  culture  the  resource  base  provided  by  the  earth  must  be  re- 

2  C.  L.  White  and  G.  T.  Renner,  Human  Geography,  An  Ecological  Study  of 
Society  (New  York,  1948),  pp.  V,  VI. 

3  Democracy  in  America. 


MEANING  AND  SCOPE  OF  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY  5 

evaluated."  4  We  shall  re-examine  these  ideas  later,  when  distinguishing 
between  political  geography  and  geopolitics. 

Political  geography,  a  subdivision  of  human  geography,  is  concerned 
with  a  particular  aspect  of  earth— man  relationships  and  with  a  special 
kind  of  emphasis.  It  is  not  the  relationship  between  physical  environment 
and  human  groups  or  societies  as  such  that  attracts  us  here  but  the  re- 
lationship between  geographical  factors  and  political  entities.  Only  where 
man's  organization  of  space  and  historical  and  cultural  influences  upon 
geographical  patterns  are  related  to  political  organizations,  are  we  in  the 
realm  of  political  geography.  In  contrast  to  the  "natural  regions"  of 
physical  geography,  the  area  units  of  political  geography  are  those  of 
states  and  nations.  To  determine  how  these  organizations  are  influenced 
by  and  adjusted  to  physiographical  conditions,  and  how  these  factors 
affect  international  relations,  is  the  aim  of  political  geography.5 

POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY  AND  GEOPOLITICS 

Since  all  political  landscapes  are  man-made,  they  are  subject  to  con- 
tinuous fluctuations.  The  politico-geographical  realities  of  today  may 
easily  become  the  myths  of  tomorrow,  and  vice  versa.  Geography,  it  has 
been  said,  does  not  argue— it  simply  is.  When  we  examine  the  changing 
relationships  of  territory  and  people,  either  within  a  state  or  between 
states,  we  are  confronted  with  artificial,  because  man-made,  structures. 
The  analysis  and  evaluation  of  the  problems  of  political  geography  are 
definitely  not  in  the  realm  of  natural  science. 

Our  approach  to  a  field  in  which  physical  geography,  political  science, 
and  economics  meet  should  be  distinguished  from  the  school  commonly 
identified  as  "geopolitics."  The  latter  goes  beyond  the  objective  study  of 
politico-geographical  factors  and  is  an  applied  pseudo-science  with  very 
questionable  objectives.  As  such,  it  has  an  axe  to  grind.  The  French 
geographer  Demangeon  correctly  labeled  geopolitics  "a  national  enter- 
prise of  propaganda  and  teaching."  At  the  point  where  geopolitics  be- 
comes a  philosophy  ( or  rather  pseudo-philosophy )  of  geographical  deter- 
minism, meant  to  justify  the  political  aims  of  a  specific  nation,  the 
curtain  is  drawn  which  separates  it  from  our  field  of  studies. 

The  philosophical  basis  of  geopolitics  is  rather  crude.  It  tries  to  draw 
its  strength  from  an  identification  of  state  and  individual.  Like  any  other 

4  P.  E.  James,  American  Geography,  Inventory  and  Prospect  (Syracuse,  1954), 
pp.  12,  13. 

5  Cf.  W.  Fitzgerald,  The  New  Europe  (New  York,  1945),  p.  1. 


6  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

living  being,  the  state  is  endowed  with  a  will  and  even  with  passions  of 
its  own.  Like  man  himself,  the  state  goes  through  the  stages  of  birth, 
growth,  maturity,  aging,  and  death.6  Hence,  as  seen  through  the  glass  of 
a  "philosophy"  of  geopolitics,  there  are  in  the  lives  of  states  "laws"  of 
growth  and  "laws"  of  decay.  Out  of  these  concepts  grow  terms  which 
readily  become  political  slogans,  such  as  "Sense  of  space,"  "Folk  without 
space,"  or  the  one  which  proved  most  effective  as  justification  of  German 
and  Japanese  expansionism,  "Living  space." 

At  the  risk  of  somewhat  oversimplifying  the  issues,  it  can  be  said  that 
the  basic  difference  between  political  geography  and  geopolitics  exists 
in  the  emphasis  on  the  effect  of  geography  on  the  dynamics  of  states  and 
nations.  The  radical  representatives  of  the  German  geopolitical  school 
held  that  geographical  factors  so  entirely  determine  growth  and  decline 
of  states  that  no  room  is  left  for  a  course  which  contradicts  the  alleged 
geographical  commands.  From  a  concept  which  looks  upon  geography 
as  the  inalienable  cause  of  human  events,  it  is  but  one  logical  step  to  a 
political  philosophy  that  claims  for  itself  the  right  to  predict  the  course 
determined  by  geographical  factors,  and  thus  to  lead  statesmen  and 
soldiers  alike  in  the  making  of  strategic  decisions.  Hence  it  is  not  surpris- 
ing to  find  the  German  geopoliticians  proclaiming  that  geopolitics  "is  the 
geographical  conscience  of  the  state."  But  the  factors  of  change  and 
fluctuations  which  daily  write  anew  the  map  of  the  world  belie  the  pre- 
tensions of  a  narrow  determinism.  More  realistically  and  more  modestly 
than  the  prophets  of  geopolitics,  most  students  of  political  geography 
hold  that  geography  does  not  determine  but  merely  conditions  the  course 
of  states.  Geography  is  but  one  of  many  tangible  and  intangible  features 
which  form  the  pattern  of  a  state.  A  significant  note  to  this  concept  of 
political  geography  has  been  added  by  French  geographers  who  stress 
the  possible  modification  of  geographical  features  as  a  result  of  man's 
technological  achievement.7 

6W.  G.  East,  "The  Nature  of  Political  Geography,"  Politica  (1937),  p.  259.  It 
should  be  noted  that  not  only  Germans  have  inclined  toward  this  biological  outlook. 
The  French  geographer  Ancel  (see  the  preface  to  his  Geopolitique,  1936)  and  the 
American  geographer  Van  Valkenburg  (Political  Geography)  were  equally  impressed. 
"The  thesis,"  R.  Hartshorne  (in  American  Geography  [Syracuse,  1954],  p.  185)  writes, 
"has  been  widely  criticized  not  only  because  of  a  lack  of  demonstration  that  the  life 
processes  of  any  state  have  led  inevitably  to  the  characteristics  that  can  be  called  old 
age  and  ultimately  to  dissolution,  but,  even  more  fundamentally,  on  the  grounds  that 
it  is  false  to  reason  from  a  superficial  analogy  between  a  biological  organism  and  a 
social  organization  operated  by  men,  since  men  collectively  through  successive  gen- 
erations are  at  no  time  older  than  their  predecessors." 

7  In  our  efforts  to  distinguish  between  geopolitics  and  political  geography,  a  note 
of  caution  is  in  order  which  is  due  to  the  semantics  of  the  term  geopolitics.  Both  terms 


MEANING  AND  SCOPE  OF  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY  7 

To  the  reader  who  has  been  taken  in  by  the  fading  glamour  of  the 
catchword  "geopolitics,"  this  brief  attempt  to  distinguish  between  geo- 
politics and  political  geography  may  appear  superficial  in  view  of  the 
amazing  fascination  which  geopolitics  evoked  during,  and  following, 
World  War  II.  To  a  large  extent  American  interest  in,  and  preoccupation 
with,  geopolitics  dates  from  the  time  of  Hitler's  military  victories.  Amer- 
ican acceptance  of  geopolitics  perhaps  resulted  from  the  actual  and 
seeming  successes  of  the  German  grand  strategy  by  what  then  appeared 
to  be  a  doctrine  and  science  on  which  the  Germans  could  claim  to  have 
a  monopoly. 

It  is  not  without  irony  that  even  before  Americans  looked  with  anxious 
fascination  upon  German  geopolitics,  its  German  monopolists  conveyed 
to  their  own  countrymen  the  idea  that  geographers  and  statesmen  in 
Britain  and  the  United  States,  and  even  in  France,  had  mastered  the 
principles  and  application  of  geopolitics  much  more  skillfully  than  was 
true  in  Germany.  In  a  symposium  by  the  editors  of  the  Journal  of 
Geopolitics,  published  in  1928,  as  well  as  in  many  editorials,  General  Karl 
Haushofer  sadly  commented  that  geographers  like  Mackinder  and  Curzon 
in  Britain,  Semple  and  Bowman  in  America,  and  Brunhes  and  Vallaux  in 
France  had  not  only  understood  the  teachings  of  Friedrich  Ratzel,  the 
father  of  political  geography  in  Germany,  much  better  than  the  Germans 
themselves  but  had  also  succeeded  in  utilizing  these  lessons  "for  the  sake 
of  power  expansion."  8 

To  Haushofer  and  his  school,  it  was  a  matter  of  serious  concern  that 
German  leadership,  both  in  the  German  Foreign  Office  and  the  General 
Staff,  excelled  in  geographic  ignorance  and  overemphasis  on  legal  train- 
ing. Hence  the  necessity  to  create  a  new  "science"  for  would-be  statesmen 
and  conquering  generals,  a  borderline  science  with  a  practical  political 
purpose.  Borrowing  heavily  from  the  disciplines  of  "geography,  history, 
and  politics,"  it  would  supply  statesman  and  officer  alike  with  the  neces- 
sary tools  for  making  political  and  strategical  decisions. 

While  the  godfathers  of  geopolitics  in  Germany  cited  with  admiration 
and  envy  the  achievements  of  political  geographers  in  the  Anglo-American 
countries,  to  convince  their  countrymen  that  a  thorough  revision  of  geo- 


are  frequently  used  interchangeably  and  it  cannot,  therefore,  be  assumed  that  the  use 
of  the  word  geopolitics  is  in  itself  indicative  of  the  author's  subscribing  to  the  beliefs 
of  geographical  determinism. 

8  Bausteine  zur  Geopolitik  (Berlin,  1928),  p.  61;  see  also,  in  rebuttal,  I.  Bowman, 
"Geography  vs.  Geopolitics,"  in  H.  W.  Weigert  and  V.  Stefansson,  eds.,  Compass  of 
the  World  ( New  York,  1954 ) ,  pp.  40-53.  Bowman  branded  Haushofer's  philosophy  of 
power  as  "utterly  dishonest." 


8  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

graphic  thinking  and  training  was  overdue  in  Germany,  the  early  vic- 
tories of  the  German  war  machine  prompted  a  similar  train  of  thought 
in  America.  As  one  American  geography  professor  put  it  in  1943:  "The 
airplane  has  created  a  new  geography  of  the  world.  Axis  leaders  knew 
this  several  years  ago  and  have  been  taking  advantage  of  it,  but  few 
Americans  are  yet  really  aware  of  it."  9  Believing  that  the  Germans  were 
more  than  a  step  ahead  of  Americans  in  supplying  statecraft  and  strategy 
with  tools  from  the  realm  of  geography,  the  American  proponents  of 
geopolitics  argued,  even  as  the  Germans,  that  it  was  high  time  to  learn 
from  the  enemy  and  to  make  geography  fashionable  by  calling  it  geo- 
politics. Thus  the  American  vogue  in  geopolitics  had  its  roots  less  in  the 
discovery  of  a  new  ( German-grown )  branch  of  political  geography  than 
in  nebulous  conceptions  and  in  the  realization  that  the  study  and  appli- 
cation of  geography  in  America  was  in  anything  but  a  perfect  state. 
Viewed  against  this  historical  background,  the  struggle  between  political 
geography  and  geopolitics  can  be  seen  in  its  proper  perspective.  Much 
less  than  a  competition  between  two  clearly  discernible  schools  of  human 
geography,  it  reflects  in  Germany  the  efforts,  during  the  ill-fated  latest 
phase  of  German  totalitarianism,  to  use,  and  often  abuse,  geography  as 
a  political  device  to  justify  acts  of  aggression  and  expansion.  At  the  same 
time,  the  awareness,  in  this  country,  of  weaknesses  in  our  own  arsenal 
of  geographical  knowledge  and  training  led  to  often  nebulous  and  mis- 
guided attempts  to  bring  geography  into  focus  by  dressing  it  as  geopol- 
itics. If  one  visualizes  the  theme  of  geography  versus  geopolitics  against 
the  historical  setting  of  the  years  surrounding  World  War  II  and  the 
ideologies  underlying  its  power  struggle,  we  shall  not  fail  to  realize  the 
temporary  nature  of  the  vastly  overblown  controversy.  This  realization 
should  make  easy  the  return  to  the  less  glamorous  but  more  solid  grounds 
of  political  geography.10 

9  Actually,  the  history  of  World  War  II  teaches  the  opposite  to  be  true  and  shows 
the  German  and  Japanese  High  Commands  as  prisoners  of  a  fatally  mistaken  Mercator 
world  view  which  caused  them  to  misjudge  completely  the  geographical  relationship 
of  the  United  States  to  the  rest  of  the  world;  cf.  R.  E.  Harrison  and  H.  W.  Weigert, 
"World  View  and  Strategy,"  in  Weigert  and  Stefansson,  op.  cit.,  pp.  74-89. 

10  For  a  more  detailed  discussion  of  German  geopolitics,  see  H.  W.  Weigert,  Gen- 
erals and  Geographers  (New  York,  1942);  R.  Strauss-Hupe,  Geopolitics  (New  York, 
1942);  E.  M.  Walsh,  "Geopolitics  and  International  Morals,"  in  Weigert  and  Stefans- 
son, op.  cit.,  pp.  12-40;  I.  Bowman,  "Geography  vs.  Geopolitics,"  Geographical  Review 
( 1942),  pp.  646-658;  and  Weigert  and  Stefansson,  op.  cit.,  pp.  40-52.  See  also  the  dis- 
cussion between  M.  A.  Junis  and  J.  O.  M.  Broek,  "Geography  and  Nationalism,"  Geo- 
graphical Review  (1945),  pp.  301-311.  All  of  these  authors  try  to  explain  and  to  de- 
bunk the  strange  phenomenon  of  geopolitics  in  Germany  as  they  saw  it  from  the  United 
States  and  hampered  by  the  fact  that  their  critical  evaluation  was  undertaken  during 


MEANING  AND  SCOPE  OF  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY  9 

Despite  its  obvious  fallacies,  geopolitics  in  Hitler  Germany  flourished 
as  one  of  the  main  roots  of  a  philosophy  which  almost  succeeded  in 
becoming  a  powerful  political  reality.  The  British  historian  H.  Trevor- 
Roper  has  highlighted  geopolitics  as  understood  and  practiced  by  Hitler 
in  an  analysis  which  we  quote  in  order  to  emphasize  the  challenge  of 
Hitler's  brand  of  geopolitics:  " 

Hitler,  like  Spengler,  saw  history  as  a  series  of  almost  geological  ages,  each 
characterized  by  a  special  "culture"  and  separated  from  the  others  by  crucial 
periods  of  transition  in  which  the  old  era,  the  old  culture,  gave  way  to  the  new. 
There  had  been  the  ancient  era  of  Mediterranean  culture,  the  medieval  era  of 
frustrated  Germanic  culture,  the  post-Renaissance  era  of  wicked  capitalist  cul- 
ture dominated  by  the  maritime  powers;  and  now  at  last— did  not  all  the  omens 
show  it?— that  era  had  in  turn  reached  its  fatal  period  and  must  be  replaced  by 
a  new.  But  what  would  this  new  era  be?  Whose  culture  would  dominate  it?  How 
would  it  be  brought  to  birth  out  of  the  dying  convulsions  of  the  old? 

To  all  these  questions  Hitler  had  thought  out  his  answer.  The  new  era  would 
be  a  "geopolitical"  era,  for  the  conquest  of  space  had  rendered  the  old  maritime 
empires  obsolete— that  was  why  he  could  afford  to  "guarantee"  the  irrelevant 
British  Empire.  It  would  be  dominated— the  geopoliticians  had  said  so— by  who- 
ever dominated  the  mass  of  Central  and  Eastern  Europe.  That  might,  of  course, 
mean  the  Russians,  who  were  more  numerous,  powerfully  organized  under  a 
totalitarian  genius  whom  he  admired,  and  already  there.  But  Hitler  did  not  want 
it  to  be  the  Russians:  he  wanted  it  to  be  the  Germans;  therefore,  in  answer  to 
the  third  question,  he  declared  that  it  would  come  about  not  by  a  natural  eco- 
nomic process  but  by  a  violent  change,  a  crusading  war  of  conquest  and  coloni- 
zation, a  war  of  giants  in  which  he,  the  demiurge  of  the  new  age,  would  bv 
sheer  human  will  power  reverse  the  seeming  inevitability  of  history  and  plant 
upon  conquered  Eurasia  that  German  culture  which  would  dominate  the  world 
for  the  next  thousand  years. 

Such  was  the  vast,  crude  vision  which  inspired  Hitler's  demonic  career— the 
vision  for  the  sake  of  which  he  had  revolutionized  and  rearmed  Germany,  ruth- 
lessly and  cunningly  solved  all  intervening  problems,  created  an  elite  of  mystical 
crusaders,  and  now,  in  June  1941,  suddenly  launched  what  would  be  for  him 
the  ultimate,  the  only  relevant  campaign:  the  Armageddon  that  was  to  decide, 
not  petty  questions  of  frontiers  or  governments,  but  the  whole  next  era  of  human 
history. 

One  further  note  of  warning  appears  necessary.  It  would  be  a  serious 
mistake  if  we  minimized  the  dangers,  to  American  thinking,  of  a  geo- 
political doctrine  and  ideology  so  firmly  rooted  in  German  soil.  It  would 


World  War  II  when  another  Iron  Curtain  separated  Hitler  Germany  from  the  Free 
World.  It  is  therefore  indispensable  for  a  better  and  unbiased  understanding  of  Ger- 
man geopolitics  to  consult  a  "critique  and  justification"  of  geographic  science  in  Ger- 
many during  the  period  from  1933  to  1945,  written  in  1941  by  a  ranking  German 
geographer,  Carl  Troll,  who  had  been  an  uncompromising  foe  of  National  Socialism 
(Annals  of  the  Association  of  American  Geographers  [1949],  pp.  99-135;  translated 
and  annotated  by  Eric  Fischer ) . 

11  "Hitler's  Gamble/'  Atlantic  Monthly  (September,  1954),  p.  42. 


10  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

indeed  be  fallacious  to  argue  that  the  issue  of  geopolitics  versus  political 
geography  is  purely  academic  in  America  for  the  reason  that  geopolitics 
was,  after  all,  a  German  product  and  not  exportable  to  America.  That 
in  a  few  exceptional  cases  American  writers  and  students  of  geography 
had  been  unduly  influenced  by  concepts  of  geopolitics,  it  could  be  argued, 
should  not  detract  from  the  fact  that  America  is  no  fertile  ground  for 
the  alien  credo. 

However,  a  comparison  between  the  basic  ideas  of  German  geopolitics 
and  of  the  American  creed  of  Manifest  Destiny  ( extending  into  Theodore 
Roosevelt's  era)  rampant  between  1830-60,  shows  that  the  German  mind 
has  no  monopoly  on  the  kind  of  argumentation  typical  of  geopolitics. 
Although  the  two  concepts  were  conditioned  by  their  different  environ- 
ments, it  appears  that  similar  centrifugal  forces  have  cast  them  off- 
similar,  but  not  identical,  for  Manifest  Destiny,  if  one  disregards  some 
of  its  more  radical  proponents,  was  in  its  original  pronouncements  not 
based  on  militarism.  The  manifest  destiny  of  the  American  Republic  was 
to  expand  over  the  continent  of  North  America  by  peaceful  process  and 
by  the  force  of  republican  principles  of  government.  Yet  the  similarities 
are  striking.  Geopolitics,  with  its  basic  concept  of  "Living  space,"  and 
Manifest  Destiny  alike  embraced  expansionism  as  a  biological  necessity 
in  the  lives  of  states  and  justified  it  by  the  conception  of  the  state  as  an 
organism.  Both  fed  on  the  theory  of  "economically  integrated  large  space 
areas."  Even  as  the  idea  of  an  economically  integrated  Central  Europe 
( Mitteleuropa )  was  part  and  parcel  of  German  geopolitics,  so  the  ter- 
ritorial expansion  of  the  United  States  westward,  southward,  and  north- 
ward became  a  battlecry  of  Manifest  Destiny  and  found  its  theoretical 
justification  in  the  principle  of  geographical  unity.  In  their  arguments, 
the  proponents  of  Manifest  Destiny  embraced  geographical  determinism 
and  vague  geopolitical  concepts  of  "natural"  frontiers.  These  played  a 
role  in  the  discussions  in  1846  over  the  Oregon  question  and  recurred 
during  the  Mexican  war.  They  found  their  strongest  expression  in  the 
geopolitical  beliefs  of  Lincoln's  Secretary  of  State,  William  H.  Seward, 
beginning  in  1860  with  his  speech  in  St.  Paul,  Minnesota,  in  which  he 
envisioned  the  peaceful  expansion  of  the  United  States  over  the  whole 
continent  of  North  America  as  the  fulfillment  of  the  will  of  Providence. 
After  the  Civil  War,  Seward's  geopolitical  ideas  revolved  around  an  even 
greater  American  empire.  They  included  the  strategic  islands  in  the 
Caribbean,  Cuba,  and  Puerto  Rico.  Looking  forward  to  possessions  in 
the  Atlantic  and  Pacific,  he  made  plans  for  a  canal  route  through  Nica- 
ragua by  ensuring  transit  rights  in  the  treaty  of  1867;  he  hoped  that  the 


MEANING  AND  SCOPE  OF  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY  11 

United  States  would  annex  the  Hawaiian  islands;  he  favored  the  annex- 
ation of  Canada.  As  the  lone  lasting  result  of  his  expansionist  endeavors 
he  was  able  to  show  only  the  acquisition  of  Alaska  from  Russia.12 

With  the  naval  historian  Alfred  Thayer  Mahan,  expansion  overseas  was 
added  to  the  credo  of  American  Manifest  Destiny  geopolitics  which, 
except  for  Seward's  dreams,  had  remained  essentially  continental.  Mahan's 
influence  went  far  beyond  the  American  scene.  It  is  difficult  to  say  whether 
it  was  more  instrumental  in  promoting  Manifest  Destiny  concepts  in  the 
United  States,  leading  her  toward  world  power  through  sea  power,  or 
whether  it  was  strongest  in  stimulating  German  expansionism,  based  on 
geopolitical  teachings  in  which  Ratzel,  influenced  by  Mahan,  had  pointed 
to  the  sea  as  an  important  source  of  national  greatness.  The  concept  of 
space,  so  essential  since  Ratzel  and  so  distorted  and  overdrawn  since 
Haushofer  and  his  disciples,  was  also  a  keynote  of  Manifest  Destiny, 
beginning  with  the  purchase  of  Louisiana  by  Jefferson.  Coupled  with 
large-space  concepts  we  find  in  latter-day  German  geopolitics  an  un- 
healthy contempt  for  the  rights  of  the  small  states  which  stood  in  the 
way  of  the  expansionist  drive  of  their  large  neighbors.  In  a  similar  vein, 
Henry  Cabot  Lodge  stated,  in  truly  geopolitical  fashion,  that  small  states 
had  outlived  their  worth  in  the  progress  of  the  world.  Even  the  racial 
and  cultural  superiority  slogans,  which  should  not  be  charged  to  the 
gospel  of  German  geopolitics  but  which  were,  however  leluctantly, 
accepted  and  adopted  by  Haushofer  and  his  group  during  the  Third 
Reich,  have  their  counterpart  in  the  pronouncements  of  the  most  radical 
prophets  of  Manifest  Destiny  in  the  United  States.  For  example,  Burgess 
foresaw  the  establishment  of  a  new  Christian  order  through  a  world 
dominion  of  Anglo-Saxons.  The  "philosophical"  basis  of  his  prediction 
was  the  concept  that  the  Teutonic  nations,  including  those  considered 
Anglo-Saxon  in  culture  and  population,  were  alone  equipped  to  assume 
leadership  in  the  formation  and  administration  of  states  and  that  they 
therefore  had  not  only  the  right  but  also  the  duty  to  subdue  other  nations 
and  to  force  organization  upon  "unpolitical  populations."  13 

Both  concepts,  then,  have  in  common  the  popular  use  of  environmental, 
especially  spatial,  factors  for  the  justification  of  power-political,  expan- 
sionist aims.  Since  their  similar  creeds  mushroomed  in  different  periods 
of  history  and  in  different  national  and  natural  environments,  dissimilar  - 

12  F.  Parella,  Lehensraum  and  Manifest  Destiny,  MA  thesis,  Georgetown  University, 
pp.  88-101;  our  discussion  of  the  relationship  between  German  geopolitics  and  Manifest 
Destiny  is  based  on  this  thesis. 

13  J.  W.  Burgess,  Political  Science  and  Comparative  Constitutional  Law,  Vol.  I 
(Boston,  1890),  pp.  30-39,  44-46. 


12  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

ities  are  obvious.  But  the  most  important  distinguishing  fact  is  that  basic 
concepts  of  geopolitics  in  Germany  became  the  official  policy  of  Hitler's 
Third  Reich,  whereas  Manifest  Destiny  was  never  adopted  as  an  official 
policy  by  the  United  States;  it  never  went  beyond  the  stage  of  a  popular 
conviction.14  Yet  the  readiness  with  which  it  was  absorbed  by  the  public 
and  by  many  in  positions  of  power  should  give  us  pause.  The  history  of 
the  Manifest  Destiny  movement  in  the  United  States  should  warn  us  not 
to  disregard  as  irrelevant  the  pseudo-philosophy  of  geopolitical  schools 
abroad,  on  the  theory  that  this  brand  of  geopolitics  was  tvpical  only  of 
the  half-forgotten  Third  Reich  in  Germany. 

THE  IMPACT  OF  CHANGE  AND  STABILITY 

Although  statistics  and  other  evidence  can  be  assembled  to  serve  the 
study  of  political  geography,  we  must  not  lose  sight  of  the  fact  that  its 
realm  is  affected  by  constant  change  and  fluctuation.  In  the  first  place, 
the  physical  environment  itself,  the  geographical  framework  within  which 
the  destinies  of  states  and  nations  unfold  themselves,  is  changing  every 
day.  Changes  in  climate,  for  instance,  and  the  resulting  effects  on  vege- 
tation, have  affected  man's  adjustment  and  consequently  his  civilizations, 
although  the  degree  of  these  influences  is  still  an  open  question.15  At 
least  as  significant  is  the  fact  that  man's  response  and  adjustment  to  his 
environment  has,  throughout  history,  undergone  constant  change  and 
evolution.  Man,  organized  in  social  and  political  groups,  has  learned 
increasingly  to  adapt  himself  to  the  conditioning  effects  of  geography. 
He  has  countered  more  and  more  successfully  the  influences  of  geograph- 
ical factors  by  making  the  best  use  of  the  opportunities  offered  him  by 
his  environment.  He  has  gone  farther,  and  by  what  has  been  described 
as  "geographical  surgery,"  he  has  molded  the  landscape  to  fit  his  needs 
or  wants. 

At  the  same  time,  it  should  be  remembered  that  the  manner  and  degree 
of  human  adjustment  to  the  natural  environment  follows  no  uniform 
pattern.  Rather,  human  societies,  whether  primitive  social  groupings  or 
highly  developed  modern  states,  have  always  varied  in  their  reaction  to 
their  environment.  To  account  for  the  basic  differences  between  nations 
in  their  response  to  environment  requires  an  examination  of  sociological 
and  psychological  characteristics  which  are  beyond  the  province  of  geog- 
raphy. However,  an  awareness  of  these  factors  helps  us  to  realize  that 

14  Parella,  op.  cit.,  p.  103. 

15  Cf.  E.  Huntington,  Mainsprings  of  Civilization  (New  York,  1945);  White  and 
Renner,  op.  cit.,  pp.  240,  241. 


MEANING  AND  SCOPE  OF  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY  13 

geographical  influence  is  but  one  of  many  conditioning  factors;  geography 
does  not  act  as  an  "agent  of  determinism." 

While  "man  has  found  it  easy  to  change  the  face  of  nature,  he  has 
found  it  difficult  to  change  his  own  mind"  ( V.  Stefansson ) .  It  has  become 
a  truism  to  speak  of  our  shrinking  world,  yet  man  individually  and 
collectively,  has  proven  his  inability  to  adjust  his  thinking  and  ideas  to 
the  changes  that  have  taken  place  in  environmental  conditions.  The  more 
mankind  has  succeeded  in  overcoming  barriers  of  terrain  and  distance, 
thus  erasing  isolation  and  bringing  about  a  closely-knit  society  of  nations, 
the  less  unity  has  the  "one  world"  of  ours  produced.  It  is  this  cultural 
lag  which  is  a  major  cause  of  political  instability  in  our  time.  One  main 
reason  for  the  cultural  lag  can  be  seen  in  the  difficulties  we  encounter 
when  we  attempt  to  adjust  political  realities  and  ideals  to  the  continuous 
change  in  the  relationship  between  man  and  his  natural  environment. 
Clearly  the  study  of  political  geography  concerns  itself  with  the  descrip- 
tion and  analysis  of  the  features  of  instability  and  change  which  permeate 
the  pattern  of  relations  between  earth  and  state.  That  necessitates  con- 
tinuous re-examination  and  re-evaluation  of  only  seemingly  established 
facts  in  the  spatial  relationship  between  states  and  political  organizations. 

We  shall  deal  on  many  occasions  with  the  changes  that  have  altered 
the  face  of  the  earth  and  we  will  find  again  and  again  that  these  changes 
have  affected  vitally  the  lives  of  nations  and  the  power  relationships  of 
every  state  in  war  and  peace.  It  does  not  matter  whether  they  are  the 
result  of  physical  processes  or  of  the  activities  of  man  himself.  The  latter 
include  changes  that  are  man-made,  such  as  canals,  or  man-caused,  such 
as  the  depletion  of  forested  lands  or  of  natural  resources,  as  well  as  those 
that  indirectly  result  from  technological  progress.  The  full  impact  of  these 
transformations,  which  in  our  time  have  succeeded  each  other  more 
rapidly  and  have  shaken  the  foundations  of  the  globe  more  terrifyingly 
than  in  any  other  epoch  of  history,  defies  human  imagination. 

We  can  think  of  no  better  illustration  of  the  magnitude  of  the  problem 
of  comprehending  the  changes  which  our  planet  is  continuously  under- 
going than  the  words  spoken  in  1827  by  the  great  German  poet  Johann 
Wolfgang  von  Goethe.  With  prophetic  imagination  he  envisaged  geo- 
graphical surgery  which  would  alter  the  face  and  structure  of  the  earth 
and  thus  revolutionize  the  relationships  of  nations.  These  are  Goethe's 
reflections  as  expressed  in  a  conversation  with  his  secretary,  Eckermann: 

...  a  passage  through  the  Isthmus  of  Panama  has  been  suggested.  Other  points 
have  been  recommended  where,  by  making  use  of  some  streams  that  flow  into 
the  Gulf  of  Mexico,  the  end  may  be  perhaps  better  attained  than  at  Panama. 


14  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

All  this  is  reserved  for  the  future,  and  for  an  enterprising  spirit.  So  much,  how- 
ever, is  certain,  that  if  they  succeed  in  connecting  the  Mexican  gulf  with  the 
Pacific  Ocean,  innumerable  benefits  will  come  to  mankind.  But  I  doubt  whether 
the  United  States  will  pass  up  the  opportunity  to  get  control  of  this  undertaking. 
I  predict  that  this  young  state,  with  its  decided  westward  course,  will,  in  thirty 
or  forty  years,  have  occupied  and  peopled  the  whole  tract  of  land  beyond  the 
Rocky  Mountains.  Along  the  entire  coast  of  the  Pacific,  which  nature  has  en- 
dowed with  the  most  capacious  and  secure  harbors,  important  cities  will  gradu- 
ally arise,  for  the  furtherance  of  much  trade  between  China  and  the  East  Indies 
and  the  United  States.  In  that  case,  it  will  become  desirable  and  even  indis- 
pensable that  a  more  rapid  communication  be  maintained  between  the  eastern 
and  western  shores  of  North  America,  both  by  merchant-vessels  and  by 
men-of-war,  and  far  superior  to  the  tedious,  unpleasant,  and  expensive  voyage 
around  Cape  Horn.  So  I  repeat,  it  is  absolutely  indispensable  for  the  United 
States  to  effect  a  passage  from  the  Mexican  gulf  to  the  Pacific  Ocean;  and  I  am 
certain  that  the  United  States  will  accomplish  it. 

Would  that  I  might  live  to  see  it!— but  I  shall  not.  I  should  like  to  see  another 
event— a  junction  of  the  Danube  and  the  Rhine.  But  this  undertaking  is  so  gigan- 
tic that  I  doubt  the  possibility  of  its  completion,  particularly  when  I  consider 
our  German  resources. 

And  third  and  last,  I  should  like  to  see  England  in  possession  of  a  canal 
through  the  Isthmus  of  Suez.  Would  that  I  could  live  to  see  these  three  great 
works.  It  would  be  well  worth  the  trouble  to  last  some  fifty  years  more.  .  .  . 

This  is  indeed  the  future  in  retrospect.  Viewed  through  the  glass  of 
an  imaginative  observer  of  the  world's  stage,  a  scene  unfolds  which  has 
become  so  obvious  a  reality  in  our  day  that  we  fail  to  grasp  easily  the 
changes  which  these  geographical  surgeries  have  caused.  They  have  not 
only  altered  our  physical  world  but  have  transformed  basically  the  power 
relations  of  the  great  national  states.  To  foresee  the  potentialities  and 
possibilities  of  change  in  state-earth  relationships,  as  Goethe  did,  is  an 
even  more  vital  task  today  than  it  was  150  years  ago.  "Is  not  the  crisis 
of  today,  which  penetrates  into  every  human  activity  and  almost  every 
larger  thought,  essentially  geographical  in  origin?"  Halford  J.  Mackinder, 
an  outstanding  British  geographer,  raised  this  question  in  1935.  He  tried 
to  answer  it  by  emphasizing  the  elementary  facts  of  our  shrinking  world. 
Mankind,  he  suggested,  has  suddenly  become  world-conscious  and  has 
taken  fright.  The  nations  have  run  to  their  homes  and  are  barricading 
their  doors.  They  have  realized  that  henceforth  they  must  live  in  a  closed 
system  in  which  they  can  do  nothing  without  generating  "repercussions 
from  the  very  antipodes."  To  grasp  the  world-wide  scope  of  modern 
geography  and  the  pattern  of  interrelationships  which  is  still  growing 
in  complexity  is  one  thing.  To  apply  the  lessons  of  this  geography,  so  that 
they  will  be  accepted  by  statesmen  and  nations,  is  altogether  different. 
Man  finds  it  easier  to  change  the  face  of  nature  than  to  change  his  own 
mind. 


MEANING  AND  SCOPE  OF  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY  15 

Although  we  have  emphasized  the  role  of  change,  which  precludes  an 
easy  explanation  of  how  geographical  factors  change  the  course  and 
destinies  of  nations,  we  must  now  equally  stress  certain  basic  geographic 
characteristics  that  possess  the  quality  of  stability.  They  have  remained 
unchanged  throughout  history,  and  an  understanding  of  these  unchange- 
able geographical  features  is  indispensable  to  statecraft  and  military 
strategy.  Historical  geography  verifies  that  the  cost  of  geographical  igno- 
rance, one  facet  of  which  is  lack  of  appreciation  of  these  unchangeable 
factors,  is  immeasurable.  Also  immeasurable  is  the  cost  of  geographical 
ignorance  due  to  lack  of  understanding  of  changes  in  the  environment  and 
their  effect  on  power  relations.  Especially  eloquent  are  those  instances 
where  nations  fell  because  of  their  failure  to  grasp  the  size  of  enemy 
territory  and  of  the  manpower  of  their  foes.  Such  ignorance  explains  the 
downfall  of  the  Greeks  when  attacked  by  Persia,  the  Jews  in  their  struggle 
with  the  Assyrians  and  Babylonians,  and  the  ultimate  defeat  of  Napoleon 
and  Hitler  in  the  vast  expanses  of  Russia.  If  we  discount  the  often  re- 
markable changes  in  the  structure  of  smaller  powers  occasioned  by  geo- 
graphical surgery,  as  in  the  case  of  Egypt  ( Suez  Canal )  or  Colombia  and 
Panama  (Panama  Canal),  the  physiographic  foundations  of  state  power 
will  in  most  cases  remain  unchanged.  Foreign  policy  and  military  strategy 
will  have  to  accept  these  foundations  as  basic;  ignorance  of  these  factors, 
both  at  home  and  abroad,  can  prove  to  be  fatal. 

It  is  a  truism  that  the  history  of  Britain  since  the  Norman  conquest 
and  her  political  and  military  decisions  have  been  clearly  based  on  her 
island  fortress  position;  her  world  power  in  the  Victorian  age  and  the 
decline  of  this  power  since  the  advent  of  the  submarine  and  the  airplane 
are  linked  to  this  geographical  fact.  In  contrast,  the  geographical  position 
of  France  has  always  been  one  of  extreme  vulnerability.  Her  exposure 
to  invasion  has  always  tempted  her  neighbors,  like  the  Hapsburgs,  who 
laid  an  iron  ring  around  France  and  later  invaded  her  territory  when  her 
internal  stability  collapsed  in  the  turmoil  of  the  French  Revolution.  The 
utter  insecurity  of  France  because  of  geographical  location— in  contrast 
to  the  security  which,  until  yesterday,  characterized  the  location  of  the 
British  Isles  and  of  the  United  States— is  documented  on  every  page  of 
her  history.  To  counteract  it,  France  has  always  been  forced  to  establish, 
often  at  high  expense,  a  friend  in  the  rear  of  her  most  dangerous  enemy, 
so  that  if  war  came  the  enemy  would  be  compelled  to  fight  on  two  fronts.16 
Thus  the  alignments  of  France  with  Sweden,  Poland,  and  Turkey  to  check 
the  expansion  of  the  Holy  Roman  Empire  and,  after  the  First  World  War, 

16  C.  Petrie,  "The  Strategic  Concept  of  Modern   Diplomacy,"   Quarterly   Review 
(1952),  pp.  289-301. 


16  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

the  creation  of  the  Little  Entente  in  Germany's  backyard  to  meet  a  future 
German  threat,  go  back  to  the  simple  facts  of  her  regional  location 
vis-a-vis  her  neighbors.  Similarly,  Germany's  strategy  in  war  and  peace 
since  the  nineteenth  century  has  been  dictated  by  awareness  of  weakness 
stemming  from  her  open  frontiers  in  East  and  West.  Statesmen  like 
Bismarck  who  knew  their  geography  designed  a  foreign  policy  for  Ger- 
many to  insure  her  against  war  on  two  fronts;  criminal  dilettantes  at  the 
helm  of  Germany,  like  Hitler,  disregarded  this  basic  policy  and  led  their 
people  into  disaster  by  attacking  their  neighbors  on  all  fronts. 

These  examples  can  be  multiplied,  and  later  we  shall  discuss  the  factors 
of  size,  shape,  and  location  in  more  detail.  They  serve  here  merely  as 
illustrations  of  stable  geographical  features  which  in  the  past  have  con- 
ditioned internal  and  external  policies  of  states  and  which  are  likely  to 
affect  the  same  decisions  in  the  present  and  in  the  future.  We  must  view 
a  country  against  this  background  of  geographical  fundamentals  in  order 
to  understand  its  role  within  the  concert  of  nations. 

THE  NEW  FRONTIERS 

The  study  of  fluctuating  frontiers,  boundaries,  frontier  zones,  and  "no 
man's  lands"  is  a  most  important  field  for  the  student  of  political  geography. 
The  day  seems  to  be  distant  when  nations  will  have  become  so  inter- 
dependent that  separating  frontiers  will  be  allowed  to  wither  away.  Until 
such  time,  the  study  of  frontiers  remains  a  vital  prerequisite  for  the  under- 
standing of  the  internal  conditions  of  a  state  and  nation  as  well  as  of  the 
international  relations  of  states. 

"The  Old  Europe  is  gone.  The  map  is  being  rolled  up  and  a  new  map 
is  unrolling  before  us.  We  shall  have  to  do  a  great  deal  of  fundamental 
thinking  and  scrapping  of  old  points  of  view  before  we  find  our  way 
through  the  new  continent  which  now  opens  before  us."  These  prophetic 
words,  spoken  by  Field  Marshal  Jan  Christian  Smuts  before  the  Empire 
Parliamentary  Association  in  November,  1943,  deserve  a  much  broader 
application.  The  old  world  is  gone  and  we  must  find  our  way  through 
the  new  continents  across  new  frontiers. 

It  is  impossible  to  describe  with  any  degree  of  stability  the  contours 
of  political  boundaries.  In  studying  problems  of  boundaries  and  frontiers, 
the  focus  is  therefore  on  instability,  expansion,  and  retraction.  We  must 
visualize  two  radically  different  world  maps  of  political  boundaries:  one 
based  on  the  boundaries  which  are  internationally  recognized,  and  the 
other  whose  lines  of  demarcation  are  in  dispute,  even  though  they  may 


MEANING  AND  SCOPE  OF  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY  17 

be  affirmed  in  legally-recognized  treaties.  The  boundaries  on  this  latter 
map  reflect  the  extension  of  national  power  by  aggressor  states. 

The  new  political  map  of  the  world  that  is  unrolling  before  us  is  indeed 
so  basically  different  from  the  map  of,  for  instance,  about  fifty  years  ago 
that  a  comparison  of  the  boundaries  of  existent  "independent"  states 
speaks  for  itself.  Nothing  illustrates  the  fluctuating  foundations  of  political 
geography  better  than  the  fact  that  in  1902  the  number  of  "independent" 
states  in  the  world  was  forty-seven  and  that,  in  1952,  it  had  increased 
by  thirty-seven  to  eighty-four.  The  following  list  records  these  relatively 
new  additions  to  the  family  of  nations.  However,  in  tracing  their  contours 
on  the  map  we  should  remember  that  their  inclusion  in  the  list  does  not 
reveal,  and  in  fact  does  in  some  cases  cloud,  the  vital  issue  of  whether 
these  states  have  by  their  legal  recognition  achieved  true  independence 
or,  if  so,  will  be  able  to  maintain  it. 

In  the  Americas,  two:  Canada,  Panama. 

In  Europe,  ten:  Albania,  Austria,  Bulgaria,  Czechoslovakia,  Finland, 
Hungary,  Iceland,  Ireland,  Poland,  Yugoslavia. 

In  Africa,  three:  Egypt,  Libya,  South  Africa. 

In  Asia,  twenty -two:  Afghanistan,  Australia,  Burma,  Cambodia,  Ceylon, 
India,  Indonesia,  Iraq,  Israel,  Jordan,  Korea,  Laos,  Lebanon,  Outer 
Mongolia,  Nepal,  New  Zealand,  Pakistan,  Philippines,  Saudi  Arabia,  Syria, 
Viet  Nam,  Yemen.17 

The  end  is  not  yet  in  sight,  as  is  illustrated  by  no  less  than  three 
territories  (Morocco,  Tunisia,  and  the  Sudan)  winning  independence 
during  the  first  quarter  of  1956.  Beferring  to  the  more  than  500,000,000 
people  of  Asia  now  living  in  territories  which  have  achieved  national 
recognition  since  1945,  the  Secretary-General  of  the  United  Nations  wrote 
in  1951  that  "one-fourth  of  the  population  of  the  world  has  gained  inde- 
pendence within  the  span  of  only  six  years.  The  pressure  of  other  depend- 
ent peoples  toward  freedom  and  equality  has  become  much  stronger  since 
the  war  and  continues  to  increase." 

THE  STUDY  OF  STATE-EARTH  RELATIONSHIPS 

Although  the  limits  that  distinguish  political  geography  from  other 
fields  of  human  geography  cannot  be  clearly  defined,  we  secure  a  firmer 
basis  for  our  study  if  we  realize  that  we  are  primarily  concerned  with 
the  relationship  between  the  state  and  its  natural  environment.  Territorv 

17  Cf.  H.  W.  Briggs,  "New  Dimensions  in  International  Law,"  The  American  Polit- 
ical Science  Review  (1952),  pp.  680  f. 


18  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

and  people  are  the  foundations  of  the  state,  but  they  are  much  more  than 
that  because  the  complex  interrelationship  between  the  two  molds  the 
structure  of  the  state  into  what  distinguishes  it  from  other  state  organ- 
izations. The  physical  environment  blends  with  the  manifold  tangible 
and  intangible  features  which  characterize  a  nation,  and  out  of  this  legion 
of  mosaic  stones  emerges  the  picture  of  a  state  with  an  individuality  of 
its  own. 

The  study  of  political  geography  deals  with  the  internal  geographical 
factors  which  contribute  to  the  state's  individuality  and,  at  the  same  time, 
with  the  geographical  factors  which  condition  the  external  relations  be- 
tween states.  In  a  "closed  system  in  which  any  major  action  within  a  state 
system  must  generate  repercussions  from  the  very  antipodes"  (Mackin- 
der),  any  attempt  to  differentiate  between  the  two  sets  of  geographical 
factors  creates  a  highly  distorted  picture.  The  patterns  of  internal  and 
external  political  geography  are  complementary. 

If  we  then  explore  the  geographical  situation  of  a  state,  or  what  is 
often  even  more  important  for  the  understanding  of  international  power 
relations,  the  geographical  situation  of  a  number  of  states  bound  together 
by  ideological  and  other  bonds,  we  must  probe  their  main  geographical 
characteristics.  Among  the  most  important,  we  may  list  size  (in  combi- 
nation with  related  factors  such  as  productivity  of  the  land,  accessibility 
through  communications,  and  climate);  location  (distinguishing  between 
the  regional  location  of  a  state  and  the  world  location'  of  a  state ) ;  and  the 
influence  which  shape  and  topography,  in  particular  the  impact  of  land 
and  sea,  have  on  national  and  international  power. 

Although  the  violent  fluctuations  affecting  areal  differentiation  of  the 
earth's  political  entities  prevents  the  construction  of  a  pure  science  system 
of  political  geography,  its  study  offers  one  significant  advantage  compared 
to  evaluation  by  regional  or  other  factors  of  geography.  This  advantage 
is  one  of  technique.  Statistical  and  other  evidence  needed  for  the  appraisal 
of  the  world's  political  units  can  be  gathered  only  within  political  bound- 
aries. Even  where  the  available  data  are  compiled  by  international 
agencies,  they  are  nevertheless  classified  by  national  units;  a  population 
census,  for  instance,  cannot  be  obtained  for  a  natural  or  cultural  region. 

In  spite  of  its  man-made  and  often  irrational  and  fortuitous  qualities, 
the  state  structure  of  the  world,  like  its  physical  structure,  offers  therefore 
a  rationale  for  geographical  analysis  and  interpretation.  The  presence  of  a 
political  boundary  is  as  significant  a  geographical  factor  as  are  soil,  relief, 
or  climate.  One  illustration  is  the  "railway  state"  organized  by  Japan  in 


MEANING  AND  SCOPE  OF  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY  19 

southern  Manchuria.  When  Russia,  in  1905,  transferred  to  Japan  control 
of  the  Southern  Manchurian  Railways,  coal  and  iron  mines,  and  a  narrow 
strip  of  land,  700  miles  long  but  only  100  square  miles  in  area,  Japan 
transformed  this  zone  into  a  new  political  entity  in  which  industries, 
villages,  and  towns  mushroomed.18  Similarly,  the  Soviet  Union  in  1954 
stepped  up  its  plans  to  assist  Communist  China  in  the  development  of  a 
new  industrial  base  in  North  China,  which,  with  the  help  of  railway 
construction,  would  draw  Northern  China,  Inner  Mongolia,  and  Sinkiang 
closer  to  the  Soviet  orbit. 

If  we  thus  focus  our  attention  on  a  political  territory  within  the  confines 
of  its  boundaries,  we  will  understand  what  distinguishes  the  study  of 
political  geography  from  that  of  regional  geography.  Political  geography 
deals  with  the  human  and  physical  texture  of  political  territories,  whereas 
regional  geography  concentrates  on  the  features  which  together  create  a 
physical  and  human  landscape,19  achieving,  both  physically  and  humanly, 
the  characteristics  of  regional  uniformity.20 

It  is  important  to  remember  that  the  "political  territory"  which  we 
have  in  mind  as  the  basis  of  politico-geographical  investigation  does  not 
need  to  be  identical  with  or  limited  to  a  state  area  and  its  internal  political 
subdivisions.  International  relations  and  politics  are  shaped  by  the  exist- 
ence of  political  units  and  regions  which  bind  together,  sometimes  firmly 
but  more  often  loosely  and  on  a  very  temporary  basis,  a  number  of 
individual  states  professing  to  share  national  and  economic  interests  and 
ideologies.  Within  such  political  areas,  there  always  exist  both  unifying 
factors  and  elements  of  disunion  and  diversity.  To  explore  both  and  to 
arrive  at  a  balanced  view  of  a  political  region  composed  of  sovereign 
states  with  common  interests  is  part  of  the  endeavor  of  the  political 
geographer.  Here  we  must  distinguish  between  areas  whose  physical 
geography  alone  justifies  their  study  in  terms  of  political  unity  or  disunity, 
and  others  which  as  the  result  of  alliances  or  international  agreements 
have  been  forged  into  political  areas  with  characteristics  of  their  own 
to  complement  those  of  the  component  states.  In  the  first  category  belong 
such  "units"  as  Latin  America  or  South  East  Asia,  "Western  Europe,"  the 
Eastern  European  satellites  bloc,  the  Balkan  countries,21  or  such  a  polit- 
ical grouping  as  the  new  British  dominion  of  Central  Africa  consisting 

18  East,  op.  cit.,  pp.  254,  267;  but  compare  the  remarks,  on  p.  19,  on  the  political 
geography  of  zones  not  identical  with  political  territories. 

19  Ibid. 

20  White  and  Renner,  op.  cit,  pp.  638-657. 

21  See  Hartshorne,  op.  cit.,  pp.  186,  187. 


20  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

of  Northern  and  Southern  Rhodesia  and  Nyasaland.22  To  the  second 
group  would  belong  units  such  as  the  NATO  countries,  or  the  wide 
expanse  of  nations  extending  from  Pakistan  to  the  Philippines  which  are 
committed  to  the  South  East  Asian  Collective  Defense  Treaty  (SEATO), 
or  the  political  realm  of  the  United  Nations. 


POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY  AND  RELATED  FIELDS 

The  close  relationship  of  historical  geography  and  political  geography 
is  evident.  The  political  geography  of  today  will  be  the  historical  geog- 
raphy of  tomorrow.  A  sound  evaluation  of  politico-geographical  factors 
is  impossible  without  consideration  of  historical  factors  and  fluctuations. 
Essentially,  the  boundary  line  between  the  two  is  one  of  emphasis  only. 
We  are  concerned  with  those  facts  and  events  of  history  and  politics 
which  can  be  described  as  "geography  set  in  motion,"  but  which  have 
not  yet  become  petrified  sufficiently  to  permit  us  to  appraise  them  mainly 
from  a  historical  viewpoint. 

More  important  than  the  distinction  between  historical  and  political 
geography  is  the  intrinsic  value  of  historical  geography  to  the  student 
of  its  sister  discipline.  For  while  history  may  not  repeat  itself,  it  is  equally 
true  that  geographical  factors  repeatedly  influence  the  destinies  of  nations. 
To  follow  the  pattern  of  geographical  influences  historically  facilitates 
the  task  of  the  political  geographer  in  exploring  the  relationship  of  state 
and  earth  as  it  exists  today  and  may  evolve  in  the  future.  We  must, 
however,  re-emphasize  that  what  in  the  early  stages  of  human  history 
appeared  as  unchangeable  physical  facts  have  been,  with  more  and  more 
rapid  revolution,  altered  by  human  action.  Whether  we  consider  major 
accomplishments  of  geographical  surgery,  through  inland  canal  systems, 
or  the  opening  of  new  territories  through  railroad  and  highway  construc- 
tion, or  the  clearing  of  forests  and  the  resulting  effect  on  the  conservation 
of  moisture,  and  thereby  fertility,  in  many  regions,  we  will  always  dis- 
cover new  documentations  of  human  action  modifying  the  physical  en- 
vironments. Alongside  such  changes  we  must  consider  the  development 
and  exploitation  of  natural  resources,  as  well  as  the  settlement  of  empty 
spaces,  in  particular  the  phenomenal  effects  of  colonization  policies  of 
the  major  powers— all  factors  which  contribute  to  affect  earth-state  rela- 
tionships. 

These  changes  and  their  impact  on  history  remind  us  that  we  would 

22  See  pp.  186,  706. 


MEANING  AND  SCOPE  OF  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY  21 

be  seriously  mistaken  in  taking  for  granted  that  the  geographical  factors 
which  conditioned  earth-state  relations  in  a  given  area  in  the  past  will 
have  the  same  conditioning  effect  today.  At  the  same  time,  the  appraisal 
still  holds  true  by  which  a  British  geographer,  more  than  thirty  years 
ago  and  before  the  advent  of  modern  aviation,  summed  up  the  relative 
significance  of  the  permanent  factors  of  geography  and  the  man-made 
changes  of  the  earth's  surface:  "Real  as  are  all  these  modes  in  which 
human  action  has  modified  the  influence  of  physical  factors,  they  are 
obviously  but  trifles  in  comparison  with  the  natural  forces  which  they 
to  a  slight  extent  counteract.  The  Alps  have  lost  their  mystery,  but  they 
still  form  a  barrier  which  must  be  crossed:  they  affect  the  cost  of  every 
parcel  of  goods  conveyed  into  or  out  of  the  valley  of  the  Po.  Civilized 
enterprise  may  seek  out  new  localities  in  which  valuable  products  can  be 
made  to  grow;  but  the  steady  working  of  the  great  natural  forces  still 
determines  climate,  with  all  its  boundless  effects  on  human  history.  Man 
may  drain  and  plant,  redeeming  a  little  space  here  and  there  from  barren- 
ness or  from  malaria:  but  all  he  has  done  or  even  can  do  is  infinitesimal 
beside  the  influence  of  the  North  Atlantic  drift,  which  is  only  one  fraction 
of  the  world's  system  of  ocean  currents."  23  Thus  it  becomes  imperative 
for  the  student  of  political  geography  to  view  his  scene  through  the  glass 
of  historical  geography;  the  lessons  of  the  past  which  explain  the  con- 
ditioning effect  of  a  country's  geography  on  its  inhabitants  will  often— not 
always— illuminate  the  clouded  scene  on  today's  stage. 

To  illustrate  the  close  bonds  between  historical  and  political  geography, 
enough  examples  could  be  cited  to  fill  a  voluminous  book.  The  one  ex- 
ample we  select  should  lead  us  to  evaluate  in  retrospect  the  internal  and 
external  geography  of  the  United  States  over  a  period  of  less  than  one 
hundred  years. 

In  his  message  to  Congress  on  December  1,  1862,  Abraham  Lincoln 
spoke  of  the  "Egypt  of  the  West."  He  defined  this  region  as  "the  great 
interior  region  bounded  east  by  the  Alleghenies,  north  by  the  British 
dominions,  west  by  the  Rocky  Mountains,  and  south  by  the  line  along 
which  the  culture  of  corn  and  cotton  meets.  ...  A  glance  at  the  map  shows 
that,  territorially  speaking,  it  is  the  great  body  of  the  Republic.  The  other 
parts  are  but  marginal  borders  to  it .  .  .  [it]  being  the  deepest  and  also  the 
richest  in  undeveloped  resources.  . .  And  yet  this  region  has  no  seacoast 
—touches  no  ocean  anywhere.  ...  [Its  people]  find  their  way  to  Europe 
by  New  York,  to  South  America  and  Africa  by  New  Orleans,  and  to  Asia 

23  H.  B.  George,  The  Relations  of  Geography  and  History,  5th  ed.  (New  York, 
1924),  p.  19. 


22  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

by  San  Francisco."  What  Lincoln  thus  described  as  the  great  body  of 
the  Republic,  the  Egypt  of  the  West,  is  the  same  Middle  West  which  since 
his  day  has  been  destined,  by  the  strength  of  the  natural  wealth  of  its 
broad  plains,  to  play  a  pivotal  role  in  the  internal  political  geography 
of  the  United  States.  To  emphasize  the  decisive  part  which  the  Middle 
West  has  always  played  in  national  politics  would  be  to  stress  the  obvious. 
More  involved  are  the  problems  which  confront  us  if  we  view  the  Middle 
West,  that  region  that  "has  no  seacoast— touches  no  ocean  anywhere," 
as  a  factor  in  the  external  political  geography  of  this  country,  both  in 
retrospect  and  from  the  ramparts  of  the  atomic  age.  When  Lincoln 
addressed  Congress  in  1862,  this  heartland  of  the  Republic  was  indeed 
safe  in  its  splendid  inland  isolation.  It  did  not  need  to  fear  attack  from 
without  as  long  as  it  wisely  refrained  from  stepping  beyond  its  ideal 
natural  frontiers.  It  is  this  historical  geography  of  the  United  States  which 
accounts  for  an  isolationism  deeply  and  justly  rooted  in  the  country's 
geography  of  yesterday  and  therefore  a  live  and  a  powerful  force  in  our 
national  and  international  policies  until  yesterday. 

At  the  height  of  the  last  World  War,  Bernard  De  Voto,24  himself  no 
isolationist,  summed  up  the  atmosphere  of  the  Middle  West  by  saying  that 

it  is  so  deep  in  the  vastness  of  the  American  continent  that  it  cannot  believe  in 
the  existence  of  salt  water.  Still  less  does  it  believe  that  beyond  the  oceans 
there  are  other  peoples  or  that  what  happens  to  such  peoples  in  any  way  affects 
what  happens  to  the  Middle  West.  It  knows  the  marginal  borders  of  its  own 
province,  the  States  east  of  the  Alleghenies  and  west  of  the  Rockies;  for  they 
also  belong  to  its  political  system.  Rut  its  awareness  stops  there,  somewhere 
inland  from  tidemark.  In  its  own  province  it  lives  an  intensive  local  life,  remark- 
ably integrated,  absorbing,  so  rich  that  it  instinctively  judges  all  other  variants 
of  American  life  to  be  less  substantial.  If  the  rest  of  America  is  insubstantial, 
Europe  and  Asia  and  Africa  are  phantoms  or  perhaps  rumors.  The  Middle  West 
is  indifferent  to  them,  even  skeptical.  Like  blizzards  and  droughts,  foreign  na- 
tions and  foreign  wars  are  temporary  and  peripheral.  When  they  require  action 
we  will  take  action— temporarily  and  on  the  periphery.  We  will  take  action  as 
militia  rising  to  repel  a  raid,  minutemen  dropping  the  plow  in  ignorance  of 
whence  the  raid  came  and  why,  and  returning  to  the  plow  doggedly  uninter- 
ested in  any  reasons  or  causes  that  have  made  us  soldiers,  killed  our  neighbors, 
and  burned  our  crops. 

De  Voto,  after  thus  evaluating  the  frame  of  mind  of  the  Midwestern 
heartland  as  he  saw  it  conditioned  by  its  natural  environment,  ventured 
to  predict  that  the  geographical  foundations  which  had  shaped  the 
political  climate  of  the  Middle  West  in  the  past  would  remain  the  same 

24  Harper's  Magazine,  June,  1943. 


MEANING  AND  SCOPE  OF  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY  23 

in  the  future.  Even  as  these  lines  are  written,  it  appears  premature  to 
pass  final  judgment  on  the  correctness  of  these  predictions: 

Some  day  the  fighting  will  stop,  the  war  will,  temporarily,  be  over.  On  that  day, 
with  a  high  and  singing  heart,  with  the  relief  of  long-impounded  energies  com- 
ing back  to  their  own  at  last,  the  Middle  West  will  pick  up  its  interrupted 
pattern.  It  will  resume  its  way  of  life.  It  will  turn  toward  the  fundamental  valley 
of  the  Mississippi,  away  from  the  oceans,  earthward  from  the  planes  which  its 
own  sons  fly  on  great  circle  courses  across  its  own  sky  to  all  the  continents  of 
the  globe.  It  will  turn  back  to  the  only  reality  it  recognizes  and  let  the  rest  of  the 
world  fade  out  beyond  the  margins  of  its  consciousness. 

John  Smith,  in  his  Generall  Historie  of  Virginia,  New  England,  and  the 
Summer  Isles,  in  1624,  memorably  phrased  an  enduring  truth:  "Geography 
without  History  seemeth  a  carcasse  without  motion,  a  History  without 
Geography  wandreth  as  a  Vagrant  without  a  certain  habitation."  And 
W.  Gordon  East,  in  an  inspiring  book,25  succinctly  defines  the  bond 
between  history  and  geography  in  these  words :  "...  in  studying  the 
inescapable  physical  setting  to  history,  the  geographer  studies  one  of 
the  elements  which  make  up  the  compound,  history:  he  examines  one 
of  the  strands  from  which  history  is  woven.  He  does  not  assert  foolishly 
that  he  can  detect,  still  less  explain,  all  the  intricate  and  confused  patterns 
of  the  tapestry.  He  does  assert,  however,  that  the  physical  environment, 
like  the  wicket  in  cricket,  owing  to  its  particularities  from  place  to  place 
and  from  time  to  time,  has  some  bearing  on  the  course  of  the  game." 
And  "Since  history  must  concern  itself  with  the  location  of  the  events 
which  it  investigates,"  it  must  continually  raise,  not  only  the  familiar 
questions  "Why?"  and  "Why  then?"  but  also  the  questions  "Where?"  and 
"Why  there?"  It  is  primarily  to  the  solution  of  the  latter  questions  that 
geography  can  contribute,  "for  it  has  been  Nature,  rather  than  Man, 
hitherto,  in  almost  every  scene,  that  has  determined  where  the  action 
shall  lie.  Only  at  a  comparatively  late  phase  of  action  does  Man  in  some 
measure  shift  the  scenery  for  himself."  26 

As  in  the  case  of  historical  geography,  it  seems  of  relatively  little 
importance  to  define  the  boundaries  which  separate  our  field  from  other 
areas  of  human  geography.  Studies  in  social,  cultural,  economic,  and 
military  geography  as  well  as  in  demography  are  legitimate  parts  of  our 
explorations  of  politico-geographical  patterns.  Without  a  discussion  of 
the  factors  accounting  for  population  growth  and  decline,  the  picture 
of  a  state  area  or  the  comparison  of  such  regions  remains  colorless.  With- 

25  The  Geography  Behind  History  (London,  1938). 

26  Ibid.,  pp.  13  and  15. 


24  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

out  a  description  of  the  economic  resources  of  a  nation,  its  strength  or 
weakness,  internally  and  in  relation  to  other  powers,  cannot  be  under- 
stood.27 This  volume,  therefore,  includes  in  its  chapters  an  analytical 
treatment  of  economic  factors  which  form  an  essential  part  of  the  intri- 
cate pattern  of  political  geography  ( in  spite  of  the  fact  that  some  of  them 
appear  to  be  but  indirectly  related  to  geography).  Without  an  appraisal 
of  the  geographical  foundations  of  military  strength,  as  expressed  in  land-, 
sea-,  and  air-power,  the  political  area  as  such  remains  an  empty  shell. 
And  the  manifold  manifestations  of  social  and  cultural  geography, 
whether  they  are  ethnic,  linguistic,  or  religious  in  nature,  form  in  a  mosaic 
the  characteristics  of  a  political  region  whose  people  in  their  tangible  and 
intangible  ways  of  life  account  for  innumerable  features  of  the  region 
not  to  be  described  in  terms  of  physical  geography.  We  cannot  escape 
the  necessity  of  including  these  various  patterns  in  our  analysis,  but  we 
must  not,  by  overemphasizing  them,  lose  sight  of  our  principal  target. 
We  will  have  to  be  careful  not  to  be  led  astray  by  psychological  patterns 
of  behavior  only  remotely  related  to  a  subject  which,  although  political, 
still  remains  essentially  geographical. 

There  is  a  fashionable  temptation  to  speculate  on  the  "character"  of 
nations  and  to  relate  it  to  their  natural  environment.  We  find  such  dis- 
tinctions as  "Latin  realism,"  "French  ingenuity,"  "English  tenacity," 
"German  discipline,"  "Russian  mysticism,"  and  "American  dynamism."  28 
Actually  the  concept  "national  character"  is  part  and  parcel  of  a  way  of 
thinking  typical  of  the  age  of  nationalism.  Its  generalizations  and  over- 
simplifications are,  from  a  scientific  viewpoint,  worthless,  the  more  so 
as  they  are  usually  made  with  the  faulty  assumption  that  the  character 
of  nations  has  the  quality  of  stability.29  No  safe  formula  has  been  found 
by  which  distinguishing  personality  traits  governing  the  behavior  of 
nations  can  be  measured.  It  seems  more  likely  that  "those  nations  en- 
danger world  peace  which,  having  the  necessary  demographic  and  eco- 

27  The  blending  of  political  and  economic  geography  is  well  illustrated  by  the 
change  of  a  book's  title  to  An  Outline  of  Political  (instead  of  Economic)  Geography 
because,  as  the  author  pointed  out  in  1941,  some  of  its  chapters  lay  less  stress  on  the 
relative  economic  resources  of  the  great  world  powers,  and  more  on  the  question  of 
the  political  organization  of  the  world  (J.  F.  Horrabin,  op.  cit.,  XI). 

28  A  typical  example  is  A.  Siegfried's  The  Character  of  Peoples,  English  translation 
L  London,  1952). 

29  C.  J.  Friedrich,  Constitutional  Government  and  Democracy  (Boston,  1941), 
p.  23;  see  also  the  critical  essay  by  G.  J.  Pauker,  "The  Study  of  National  Character 
Away  from  that  Nation's  Territory,"  in  Studies  in  International  Affairs  (Cambridge, 
Mass.,  June,  1951). 


MEANING  AND  SCOPE  OF  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY  25 

nomic  resources,  are  governed  by  men  for  whom  maximization  of  power 
is  the  supreme  value,  than  that  the  danger  comes  from  'national  character.' 
The  threat  came  from  Frenchmen  led  by  Napoleon  at  one  time,  from 
Germans  led  by  Hitler,  Italians  by  Mussolini  and  Japanese  by  their 
militarists  at  another  time,  from  Russians  and  Chinese  governed  by 
Communist  Politbureaus  at  present."  30  It  must  therefore  be  concluded 
that  no  useful  purpose  in  the  exploration  of  politico-geographical  factors 
will  be  served  by  the  introduction  of  such  nebulous  features  as  "the 
character"  of  nations. 

Although  this  warning  appears  necessary  to  avoid  the  introduction  of 
sociological  and  psychological  considerations  which  are  but  loosely,  if 
at  all,  related  to  the  realm  of  political  geography,  it  would  be  equally 
fallacious  to  take  too  narrow  a  view  of  the  geographical  confines  of  the 
study  of  political  geography.  Its  scene  is  not  necessarily,  and  not  limited 
to,  the  political  area  of  a  state  or  of  interrelated  states.  Looking  beyond 
shifting  political  boundaries,  we  will  profit  from  exploring  connections 
between  physical  environment  and  national  groups  or  nations  as  distin- 
guished from  states.  Political  geography,  if  limited  to  the  study  of  land- 
scapes affected  by  the  activities  of  a  state  or  of  states,  would  produce 
incomplete  and  often  distorted  pictures.  As  especially  a  number  of  French 
geographers  have  emphasized,  the  structure  and  the  activities  of  states 
within  their  natural  setting  can  be  better  evaluated  if  we  include  in  our 
studies  the  nation  and  such  national  groups  which  account  for  the  strength 
or  weakness  of  a  state.  The  political  boundary  of  a  state  represents  there- 
fore no  boundary  for  our  explorations.  The  ethnic,  linguistic,  religious 
affiliations  of  national  groups  are  not  altogether  halted  by  political  bound- 
aries. In  many  respects  the  cultural  landscape,  which  is  formed  by  zones 
of  religion,  of  language,  or  of  ethnic  relationships,  even  of  common 
denominators  of  literacy  and  illiteracy,  acquires  the  characteristics  of  a 
political  landscape.  As  such  it  belongs  to  the  domain  which  the  student 
of  political  geography  will  have  to  explore.31 

30  Pauker,  op.  cit.,  p.  99. 

31  Q.  Wright,  The  Study  of  International  Relations  (New  York,  1955),  undertakes 
in  a  chapter  on  "Political  Geography"  a  critique  of  what  he  claims  has  been  the  hope  of 
some  geographers  that  because  of  the  apparent  permanence  of  geographical  conditions, 
geography  might  become  the  master  science  of  international  relations.  He  states,  cor- 
rectly, that  this  hope  seems  to  be  in  vain.  We  agree  with  his  conclusion  that  political 
geography,  in  order  to  develop  a  general  theory  of  international  relations,  must  be 
combined  with  demography  and  technology  as  well  as  with  "social  psychology,  soci- 
ology, and  ethics."  In  other  words,  it  contributes,  together  with  other  equally  signifi- 
cant disciplines,  to  the  understanding  of  internal  and  external  power  relations. 


CHAPTER 


2 


Si 


i^e 


SIZE— A  BASIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

Political  geography  deals  with  the  political  organizations  of  men  on  the 
face  of  the  globe.  As  the  globe  has  only  a  limited  surface,  the  division 
of  this  surface  between  political  units— their  size— becomes  a  basic  factor. 
Some  geographers  have  shied  away  from  recognizing  size  as  a  basic 
factor  in  political  geography.1  There  is  however,  no  escape  from  the  fact 
that  political  units  are  of  different  size  and  that  their  political  behavior 
is  in  part  determined  by  the  size  of  their  territories  as  well  as  the  size 
of  other,  especially  of  adjacent,  political  units.  In  order  to  understand 
political  behavior,  it  is  therefore  necessary  to  evaluate  the  size  of  the 
political  unit. 

"SPACE"  IN  GEOPOLITICS 

In  the  terminology  of  geopolitics,  it  became  fashionable  to  talk  of  space 
(Raum)  rather  than  of  size.  This  concern  with  space  had  become,  even 
before  the  Haushofer  school  achieved  prominence,  a  veritable  obsession 
of  many  German  geographers  who  felt  that  Germany  had  too  little 
"living  space"  (Lebensraum).  The  proponents  of  geopolitics  were  con- 
vinced that  British  and  American  geographers  had  come  to  take  for 
granted  the  spatial  advantages  of  their  countries  and  were  apt  to  overlook 
the  importance  of  space  for  other  countries.  However,  this  dichotomy 
between  German  and  Anglo-Saxon  political  geographers  should  not  be 

1  R.  Hartshorne,  "Functional  Approach  in  Political  Geography,"  Annals  of  the 
Association  of  American  Geographers  (lune,  1950),  p.  99. 

26 


SIZE  27 

overrated.2  It  was  an  American  geographer,  Ellen  Churchill  Semple, 
inspired  by  Ratzel  and  in  full  agreement  with  what  was  to  become  the 
gospel  of  the  Haushofer  school,  who  wrote:  ".  .  .  for  peoples  and  races 
the  struggle  for  existence  is  at  bottom  a  struggle  for  space."  3  On  the  other 
hand,  not  all  students  of  political  geography  in  Germany  succumbed  to 
the  emotional  connotations  of  the  geopolitical  school  and  some  continued 
to  use  the  term  space  (Raum)  as  a  synonym  for  territory,  stressing  the 
intimate  connection  of  state  and  territory. 

The  emphasis  on  "space"  in  Germany  can  be  traced  to  Friedrich  Ratzel, 
but  in  his  writings  it  has  not  yet  the  character  of  a  slogan  and  of  a  political 
battle  cry  which  it  acquired  with  Haushofer.  The  concepts  of  space  and 
size  are  not  entirely  interchangeable,  because  space  is  boundless  and  is 
therefore  not  mathematically  measurable,  while  size  is  determined  by 
known  dimensions.  Geographic  space,  however,  implies  a  definite  location 
and  an  area  of  a  certain  size.  There  is  also  the  mystical  and  emotional 
connotation  which  clouds  the  meaning  of  "space"  in  geopolitical  liter- 
ature. Because  the  term  space  can  equally  be  used  both  loosely  and  lit- 
erally, it  is  possible  to  use  it  vaguely  and  still  with  the  pretension  of 
accuracy.  From  this  ambiguous  use  the  mystical  connotation  of  the  terms 
space  and  living  space  evolved.  For  this  reason,  we  prefer  the  use  of  the 
term  size,  even  where  it  would  be  possible  to  speak  of  space,  and  shall 
thus,  aware  of  the  semantic  implications,  use  the  term  space  only  cau- 
tiously and  where  it  has  a  definite  meaning. 

MOTIVATION  FOR  EXPANSION  IN  SPACE 

The  size  of  political  units  varies  within  rather  wide  limits.  For  a  number 
of  states  the  available  space  within  these  limits  seems  too  confining.  One  of 
the  motivating  impulses  in  man,  though  not  necessarily  the  dominant  one, 
is  the  "will  to  power."  4  Individuals,  becoming  leaders  of  nations,  often 
try  to  exert  their  "will  to  power"  through  enlarging  the  power  of  their 
nations;  in  the  international  sphere  the  will  to  power  expresses  itself  in 
the  desire  to  dominate  large  areas.  Even  where  this  motivation  can  be 
discounted,  the  fact  remains  that  nations  generally  strive  to  improve  their 
living  standards,  or  at  least  try  to  maintain  them  despite  a  growing 
population.  From  the  geographer's  point  of  view,  there  are  three  pos- 
sible ways  to  accomplish  such  a  goal.  One  is  to  utilize  space  within  a 

2  See  pp.  7  f. 

3  Influences  of  Geographical  Environment  (New  York,  1911),  p.  188. 

4  The  German  philosopher  Nietzsche  built  a  philosophical  system  around  the  as- 
sumed pre-eminence  of  this  psychological  trait. 


28  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

country's  boundaries  which  was  heretofore  unused.  However,  the  possi- 
bilities of  internal  colonization  are  limited,  unless  the  colonization  is 
accompanied  by  technological  progress  and  a  corresponding  expansion 
of  communications.  Internal  colonization  is  therefore  often  possible  only 
in  connection  with  the  second  method,  intensification  of  available  space. 
This  second  method  has  been  used  in  all  of  the  great  periods  of  human 
history,  from  the  time  when  Egyptians  and  the  nations  of  Mesopotamia 
united  to  devise  their  grand  river  regulations  and  irrigation  canals  to  our 
modern  period  of  industrialization  and  urbanization.  But  nations  and 
their  leaders  have  at  many  times  also  tried  the  third  alternative  and  have 
often  preferred  to  reach  the  desired  goal  by  expanding  their  territories 
through  war,  by  taking  the  lands  of  their  neighbors  and  expelling  or 
exterminating  the  inhabitants,  or  forcing  them  to  work  for  their  con- 
querors. 

This  third  method  of  maintaining  and  improving  living  standards 
seemed  the  only  one  available  to  nomadic  herdsmen  in  times  of  drought 
or  when  a  major  population  increase  and  the  consequent  increase  in 
number  of  their  cattle  forced  them  to  migrate  or  to  expand.  In  nomadic 
society  there  is  generally  little  or  no  unused  space  available;  intensifica- 
tion of  animal  husbandry  is  generally  impossible  on  the  nomadic  level 
of  civilization  and  technology.  Conquest  as  alternative  to  starvation  thus 
appears  as  the  only  solution.  In  our  time,  nomadism  as  a  power  factor 
has  practically  disappeared.  However,  expansion  -of  territory  through 
conquest  never  was  limited  to  nomads.  Whether  under  the  slogan  of 
"conquest  for  living  space"  or  with  some  other  justification,  it  has  re- 
mained the  most  usual  weapon  in  the  struggle  to  maintain  or  to  improve 
living  standards.  Because  conquest,  even  if  undertaken  for  the  sake  of 
escaping  starvation,  results  in  increased  power,  conquering  nations  have 
often  gone  much  farther  than  can  be  justified  by  their  original  aims. 
Successful  conquerors  are  led  from  one  goal  to  the  next.  Hitler  the  con- 
queror, and  Communism  the  conquering  ideology  are  embodiments  of 
age-old  phenomena. 

THE  WORLD  STATE 

The  theoretical  extreme  limit  of  size  which  a  political  unit  can  attain 
would  be  a  state  embracing  the  entire  world.  Whether  such  a  state  would 
still  belong  to  the  legitimate  field  of  investigation  for  the  political  geogra- 
pher is  an  academic  question.  However,  the  problem  has  some  meaning 
in  historical  geography,  if  applied  in  a  restricted  sense  to  such  world 
powers  as  the  Roman  Empire,  the  ancient  Chinese  Empire,  and  possibly 


SIZE  29 

such  empires  as  the  Incan  and  Mayan  empires.  These  occupied  what 
indeed  was  at  their  time  known  as  the  entire  world,  or  what  appeared 
worth  conquering,  thus  excluding  inhospitable  regions,  thinly  settled  by 
despised  barbarians.  Today  the  known  world  coincides,  for  all  practical 
purposes,  with  the  whole  surface  of  the  globe.  Thus  size  can  never  be 
valued  absolutely  but  only  in  relation  to  the  conditions  prevailing  in  a 
given  period. 

POLITICAL  UNITS  WITHOUT  TERRITORY 

On  the  other  end  of  the  scale  from  world  statehood  are  political  units 
without  any  territorial  extent.  It  is  open  to  question  whether  such  a  unit 
can  accurately  be  named  a  "state";  most  political  geographers,  however, 
will  regard  a  discussion  of  the  geographic  problems  surrounding  such 
organizations  as  the  League  of  Nations  or  the  United  Nations  as  within 
the  scope  of  their  interests.  Actually  in  such  organizations  the  idea  of  the 
global  state  and  of  political  bodies  without  space  meet  and  merge  into 
one. 

THE  PAPAL  STATE 

The  organization  of  the  Roman  Catholic  Church  presents  another 
interesting  marginal  problem.  There  is  nothing  comparable  in  any  other 
religious  organization,  not  even  in  the  often  compared  state  of  the  Dalai 
Lama  in  Tibet.  The  Pope,  as  head  of  the  Roman  Catholic  Church,  is 
also  the  head  of  a  state  in  central  Italy.  His  temporal  power  goes  back 
to  the  days  of  the  declining  Roman  Empire.  In  1871,  the  Papacy  lost  its 
worldly  dominions  and  these  were  not  restored  until  1929,  when  the 
Church  and  Mussolini  concluded  the  Lateran  Treaty.  Since  then  the  Pope 
has  ruled  again  as  spiritual  head  over  the  Catholics  of  the  world  from 
the  tiny,  independent  state  of  the  Vatican  City. 

HISTORICAL  REMNANTS 

The  Papal  state  can  be  regarded  also  as  a  historical  remnant.  In 
Germany,  until  its  occupation  by  Napoleon's  armies,  many  tiny  ecclesiastic 
states  existed.  Very  often  the  secular  territory  of  an  archbishop,  bishop, 
or  abbot  was  looked  upon  as  the  indispensable  basis  for  his  spiritual 
dominion.  All  these  ecclesiastic  and  feudal  states  have  disappeared.  Only 
the  Papal  state  remains. 

Other  historical  size-power  anachronisms  include  the  still-used  power- 
suggestive  titles  of  emperor,  or  king  of  kings  by  rulers  of  such  countries 


30  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

as  Ethiopia,  Iran,  and  Annam.  Equally  disproportionate  in  terms  of  size, 
at  least,  is  the  position  of  Taiwan-based  Free  China  among  the  Big  Five, 
those  states  which  alone  exert  veto  power  in  the  United  Nations.5 

EVOLUTION  OF  STATE  POWER  AND  THE  FACTOR  OF  SIZE 

In  general,  military  and  economic  power,  size  of  territory,  and  rank 
are  commensurate.  There  are  states  whose  size  has  remained  constant, 
but  whose  power  has  grown  in  spite  of  the  lack  of  territorial  growth. 
These  are  the  countries  whose  spaces  have  been  filled  with  people,  as 
in  Argentina;  or  countries  in  which  new  resources  have  been  discovered 
and  their  use  organized  for  the  good  of  the  country,  as  in  Mexico  and 
other  countries  with  exploitable  oil  resources;  or  in  countries  such  as 
Canada  and  the  U.S.S.R.  which  succeeded  in  transforming  prairies  into 
wheat  lands  and  in  extending  northward  their  limits  of  agricultural 
activities.  There  are  again  other  nations  which,  established  for  many 
centuries  within  their  present  boundaries,  have  maintained  the  size  of 
their  territory  to  the  present  day.  Denmark  and  Switzerland  have  almost 
exactly  the  same  size  as  they  had  five  centuries  ago,  although  their  pop- 
ulations have  multiplied.  Whereas  once  her  territory  was  sufficiently  large, 
populous,  and  rich  to  warrant  a  significant  position  in  European  or  even 
world  affairs,  Switzerland's  political  power  potential  today  has  significance 
only  because  of  the  defensive  possibilities  of  its  mountains,  and  Danish 
statesmen  in  the  1930's  liquidated  their  military  establishment  completely 
because,  within  the  country's  small  territory,  it  did  not  seem  possible  to 
defend  it  against  aggressors.  Both  Denmark  and  Switzerland  still  rank 
as  important  members  of  the  European  community  of  nations,  but  only 
because  of  their  high  cultural  standing  and  strong  economic  position,  not 
because  of  the  size  of  their  territory  or  population. 

REMAINDERS  OF  SMALL  FEUDAL  STATES 

Feudal  states  still  exist  in  Europe  essentially  in  the  same  form  as 
centuries  ago.  Some  of  these  are  tiny  sovereign  monarchies  such  as 
Monaco  (370  acres),  and  Liechtenstein  (62  square  miles).  Some  are 
republics,  such  as  San  Marino  (38  square  miles),  and  Andorra  (191 
square  miles).  In  India,  scores  of  such  small  feudal  states  have  disap- 

5  The  island  of  Taiwan  ( 13,890  square  miles )  is  about  twice  the  size  of  Massa- 
chusetts (7,867  square  miles)  or  New  Jersey  (7,522  square  miles).  Its  population, 
in  1950,  totalled  7,647,000  which  equals  that  of  Texas  (263,513  square  miles). 


SIZE  31 

peared  only  since  the  country  gained  independence  in  1948  and  merged 
them  into  princely  federations.  Others  are  administered  centrally.  Even 
after  this  consolidation  process,  the  Saurashtra  Union  has  a  territory  of 
only  21,062  square  miles  in  spite  of  the  fact  that  it  succeeded  not  less 
than  222  states,  including  dwarf  states  of  several  acres.  The  Patiala  and 
East  Punjab  States  Union  is  still  smaller  ( 10,099  square  miles ) .  However, 
a  new  reform  program  proposes  to  wipe  out  these  remnants.  Among 
other,  centrally-administered,  territories,  such  small  states  as  Tripura 
(4,049  square  miles)  have  not  completely  lost  their  identity.  Within 
Pakistan  a  few  states,  such  as  Chitral  (4,000  square  miles),  Swat  (1,000 
square  miles ) ,  and  Khairpur  ( 6,050  square  miles ) ,  have  retained  approx- 
imately the  same  position  they  had  under  British  rule. 

In  contrast  to  the  consolidation  process  under  way  in  India  and  Paki- 
stan, we  find  in  the  Malayan  Peninsula  native,  essentially  feudal  sultanates. 
These  have  successfully  resisted  consolidation  in  their  effort  to  protect 
themselves  from  Chinese  and  Indian  immigrant  communities  such  as  have 
become  majority  populations  in  other  parts  of  the  Peninsula.  In  Europe, 
the  complicated  pattern  of  close  to  one  hundred  dwarf  states  which  once 
constituted  the  political  map  of  Germany,  has  changed  radically  since 
Napoleon  I  erased  most  of  these  states  from  the  map.  A  few  managed 
to  survive  into  the  period  of  the  Third  Reich  and  were  then  finally  in- 
corporated into  larger  political  units.  It  was  their  very  smallness  that 
contributed  to  their  preservation  for  such  a  long  time;  their  smallness  was 
also  a  factor  in  the  preservation  of  anachronistic  feudal  features.  The 
smallest  modern  state  which  is  more  than  a  feudal  remnant  is  Luxembourg 
(999  square  miles),  which  is  distinguished  for  its  iron  ore  deposits,  its 
highly-developed  steel  industry,  and  its  dense  population  of  290,000. 
Despite  its  small  size,  and  due  to  its  economic  and  constitutional  devel- 
opment, Luxembourg  has  been  able  to  preserve  its  independence,  but 
only  as  a  partner  of  other  states  in  customs  and  economic  unions.  At 
present  it  is  one  of  the  three  members  of  the  Benelux  combination, 
Belgium  and  the  Netherlands  being  the  other  partners. 

FEUDAL  STATES  OF  LARGER  SIZE 

Where  feudal  states  of  larger  size  have  carried  over  into  the  twentieth 
century,  we  can  generally  observe  a  process  of  transformation  or  breaking 
up  into  smaller  units.  In  India,  the  more  progressive  princely  countries, 
such  as  Mysore  and  Travancore,  survived  in  but  slightly  changed  form. 
The  largest  and  strongest  feudal  princely  state,  that  of  the  Nizam  of 


32  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

Haidarabad,  became  a  victim  of  the  Indian  transformation.  This  process 
is  not  limited  to  Asia.  It  is  paralleled  by  what  happened  two  decades 
earlier  in  Europe  when  the  semi-feudal  Austro-Hungarian  monarchy  of 
the  Hapsburgs  broke  up  in  the  turmoil  of  the  defeat  of  the  central  powers 
in  1918.  The  semi-feudal  nature  of  the  Hapsburg  realm  is  obvious  from 
the  fact  that  in  spite  of  parliamentary  institutions  it  was  still  regarded 
as  the  personal  estate  of  the  emperor. 

CITY-STATES 

Historically  of  great  importance,  and  by  far  the  most  notable  of  all 
small  states,  are  city-states.  Greek  city-states  formed  the  geographical 
basis  of  the  political  philosophy  of  Aristotle  and  Plato,  who  extolled  the 
advantages  of  the  small  state.  The  failure  of  the  Greeks  to  develop  polit- 
ical power  on  a  scale  commensurate  with  the  wide  sphere  of  their  cultural 
influence  is  in  part  due  to  their  inability  to  free  themselves  from  the 


10     20     30     40      50  Mi 


0   10  20   30   40   50  Km 


Fig.  2-1.  Danzig— 1919-1939. 


SIZE 


33 


Fig.  2-2.  Short-lived  City-states  at  the  Head  of  the  Adriatic  Sea:   (1)  boundary  after 
World  War  I;  ( 2 )  boundary  after  World  War  II;  ( 3 )  boundary  in  1955. 

limitations  of  the  city-state  concept.6  We  can  trace  city-states  in  various 
parts  of  the  world,  in  Phoenicia  and  Greece,  in  India,  in  some  American 
Indian  areas,  and  in  medieval  Germany  and  Italy.  Among  many  German 
city-states,  only  Bremen  and  Hamburg  have  survived  as  constituent  mem- 
bers of  the  German  Federal  Republic.  In  spite  of  their  great  historical 
importance,  city-states  have  largely  disappeared  as  sovereign  states. 

In  recent  years  attempts  have  been  made  to  revive  small-sized  city- 
states,  the  express  purpose  being  to  avoid  creating  a  state  which  could 
exert  power  of  its  own.  Danzig  (708  square  miles)  (Fig.  2-1)  and  Fiume 
(8  square  miles)  (Fig.  2-2)  were  set  up  after  World  War  I  in  order  to 
give  their  overwhelmingly  German  and  Italian  populations  freedom  from 


6  Semple,  op.  cit.,  pp.  195-196. 


34  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

the  rule  of  Poland  and  Yugoslavia,  for  which  countries  the  cities  served 
as  main  harbors.  Their  smallness  was  expected  to  remove  any  danger 
that  they  would  ever  be  able  to  cut  off  these  countries  from  the  sea. 
When  these  city-states  did  not  fulfill  the  hopes  placed  in  them,  they  soon 
disappeared.  Nevertheless,  the  experiment  was  repeated  after  World 
War  II  in  Trieste.  The  turbulent  history  of  this  experiment  illustrates  the 
manifold  problems  resulting  from  such  constructions. 

In  an  interesting  experiment  in  West  Africa,  British  colonial  rule  is 
making  an  effort  to  preserve  the  threatened  unity  of  Nigeria  by  the 
establishment  of  an  autonomous  city.  Lagos,  the  capital  as  well  as  the 
port  of  the  Nigerian  federation  of  conflicting  provinces,  was  in  1953 
separated  from  the  Western  Provinces  and  given  autonomous  status,  in 
order  to  preserve  its  vital  services  for  all  members  of  the  federation. 

CITY-STATES  AND  COLONIZATION 

The  declining  power  of  the  city-state  on  the  political  map  of  the 
twentieth  century  should  not  overshadow  the  importance  of  dependent 
city-states  in  historical  geography  and  in  the  geography  of  colonization. 
For  a  long  time,  such  autonomous  city-states  with  an  independent  basis 
for  trade  and  navigation  have  played  a  significant  part  as  advance  posi- 
tions for  colonial  growth.  When  the  Portuguese,  after  a  voyage  of  many 
months,  reached  India,  they  established  along  its  coast  fortified  places 
which  were  destined  to  carry  on  trade  with  the  hinterland  during  the 
long  periods  between  visits  of  the  fleets.  These  Portuguese  factories  in 
India  were  in  the  medieval  tradition  of  the  Italian  factories  in  the  Levant.7 
They  eventually  grew  away  from  their  distant  places  of  origin  and  as  a 
result  of  various  sociological  factors  and  of  the  ability  of  the  colonizers 
to  mix  with  the  native  population,  a  distinctive  non-Indian  national  feeling 
developed,  at  least  among  the  Goanese,  the  native  inhabitants  of  the 
largest  of  these  city-colonies.  The  new  India,  growing  into  the  role  of 
an  independent  nation,  has  become  apprehensive  about  what  she  con- 
siders an  outdated  continuation  of  Portuguese  colonial  rule  on  Indian  soil 
(Fig.  2-3). 

While  only  Goa,  with  its  population  of  about  700,000,  appears  to  have 
developed  a  distinctive  individuality  of  its  own,  we  find  along  the  Indian 

7  The  Italian  cities  Venice,  Genoa,  and  Pisa  founded  autonomous  colonies  in  Pal- 
estine, in  Syria,  and  on  Cyprus,  and  in  the  Byzantine  Empire  at  the  period  of  the 
Crusades. 


SIZE 


35 


^3? 

p., 

I 

« 

V 


,.*/v. 


u 


USSR         \ 


V 


AFGHANISTAN     ;'  7  N—./ 

*J      (  Kmm  C' 


/ 


nS 


; 


TIBET 


X 


V_.        5IKKIM.        ..*■  t  I  .  , 

\.  NEPAL  "^-Tj/lHUTAN*       ly  /,' 

>     V"<>  } 

X       EAST  f/l      y.<J 

?      PA  VICT  AM       \  .,  '  4 


f 

,4      BURMA 


Fig.  2-3.  Portuguese  and  French  ( 1954 )  Colonial  Holdings  in  India. 

Coast  other  city-colonies,  small  fragments  of  Portuguese  territory  which, 
as  remnants  of  trading  stations  in  India,  have  ironically  survived  the 
greater  empire  of  Britain. s  Other,  and  more  significant,  examples  are  the 
endangered  British  gate-city  to  China,  Hong  Kong,  the  Soviet  Union's 

8  W.  G.  East  and  O.  H.  K.  Spate,  The  Changing  Map  of  Asia  (London,  1950), 
p.  152. 


36  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

ice-free  harbor  in  Manchuria,  Dairen,9  and  the  British  guardian  of  the 
south  entrance  to  the  Red  Sea,  Aden.  The  Hong  Kong  situation,  in  par- 
ticular, is  one  of  instability  in  the  light  of  constant  and  growing  tensions. 
Pressure  for  a  plebiscite  may  eventually  revert  the  crown  colony  to  China; 
its  population  which  had  totalled  850,000  in  1931  and  which  as  a  result 
of  the  influx  of  refugees  from  China  was  estimated  in  November,  1952, 
at  2,250,000,  included  only  a  total  of  13,000  British  subjects  of  European 
race.10 

Thus,  while  the  balance  of  power  between  the  major  Asian  and 
European  nations  has  maintained  the  city-colony  beyond  other  forms  of 
dwarf  states,  these,  too,  tend  to  disappear  gradually  from  the  political 
scene.  Some  city-states  have  served  as  the  basis  for  larger  colonies  and 
states,  as  Rome  did  in  ancient  times.  Bombay  has  expanded  into  one 
of  the  largest  provinces,  now  states,  of  India;  the  little  city-colony  of 
New  York,  because  the  entrance  gate,  to  a  powerful  state  of  the  Union. 
This  trend  toward  larger  political  units  is  evident  if  one  compares  the 
distant  past  with  the  present.  Athens,  Sparta,  Corinth,  Tyre,  and  Sidon  in 
ancient  times,  and  Venice,  Genoa,  and  Pisa  in  the  Middle  Ages,  ranked  as 
big  powers.  Today,  no  nation  with  so  small  a  territorial  basis  could  be  re- 
garded as  a  great  power.  Even  such  states  as  Portugal  or  the  Netherlands, 
though  great  powers  in  the  sixteenth  to  eighteenth  centuries,  could  not 
play  an  analogous  role  today. 

The  discrepancy  in  size  of  territory  in  these  instances  is  much  more 
striking  than  the  discrepancy  in  size  of  population.  Athens  in  the  4th 
century  B.C.  finally  succumbed  to  the  Macedonian  territorial  state.  How- 
ever, it  might  be  fairly  doubted  whether  Athens  ( including  its  dependent 
island  cities  in  the  Aegean,  or  even  without  them)  was  the  inferior  in 
population  of  the  two  powers.  Throughout  Greek-Roman  antiquity  1X  in 
the  Mediterranean  area,  the  majority  of  the  free  population  lived  in  city- 
states.  Probably  only  since  the  time  of  the  declining  Roman  Empire  has 
the  population  of  territorial  units  grown,  while  that  of  the  cities,  with 
few  exceptions,  proportionately  shrank. 

9  Dairen  was  returned  to  China  in  May,  1955. 

10  The  Statesman's  Yearbook,  1955,  p.  238;  Focus  (November  3,  1953),  Hong  Kong. 

11  It  should  be  noted  in  passing  that  antiquity  and  the  Middle  Ages  had  also  their 
overlarge  states,  such  as  the  Persian,  Roman,  and  Mongolian  Empires.  Nobody,  so  far, 
has  based  on  the  disappearance  of  such  empires  ( which  embraced  most  of  their  known 
worlds)  a  theory  of  a  trend  to  a  proliferation  of  independent  smaller  states. 


SIZE  37 

THE  METROPOLITAN  CITY 

Far  into  the  nineteenth  century  urban  populations  constituted  a  small 
proportion  of  the  world  population.  The  rapid  growth  of  the  modern  city, 
which  made  the  largest  of  them  more  populous  than  some  medium-sized 
nations,  has  not  found  a  political  expression  in  the  international  field. 
Paris,  London,  or  New  York  have  a  larger  population  than  Norway,  Den- 
mark, Switzerland,  or  Uruguay— greater  New  York  even  more  than  Bel- 
gium, the  Netherlands,  Portugal,  or  a  majority  of  the  Latin  American  or 
Arab  nations.  Historically,  such  metropolitan  areas  sometimes  have  been 
given  the  status  of  provinces  or  member  states.  Berlin  became  one  of 
the  Prussian  provinces,  Vienna  one  of  the  nine  constituent  states  of  the 
Austrian  federative  republic.  Neither  can  be  called  a  genuine  city-state. 
Still  less  is  this  true  of  Washington,  D.C.,  of  the  City  of  Mexico,  or  of 
Canberra,  the  capital  of  Australia. 

All  this  points  to  the  conclusion  that  under  modern  conditions  the 
growth  of  metropolitan  areas  is  rather  a  function  of  the  development  of 
the  country  than  an  independent  phenomenon.  However,  while  the 
growth  of  metropolitan  areas  is  a  function  of  a  growing  country  (as  in 
the  doubling  of  the  population,  in  ten  years,  of  the  twin  cities  of  Delhi 
and  New  Delhi),  the  decline  of  a  nation  is  not  necessarily  indicated  by 
a  decline  of  population  in  its  main  cities.  Only  in  extreme  cases  does 
such  a  development  occur,  such  as  in  the  case  of  Vienna  and  Istanbul. 
Both  had  been  capitals  of  empires  of  30  to  50  million  inhabitants  and 
both  went  down  in  World  War  I.  Both  cities  lost  up  to  25  per  cent  of 
their  population,  with  Vienna  becoming  the  capital  of  the  new  Austria 
with  a  population  of  6M  million,  and  Istanbul  becoming  the  main  port 
city  of  a  country  of  12  million. 

THE  SUPER  POWERS 

The  global  scene  of  our  time  is  dominated  by  the  emergence  of  the 
United  States  and  the  Soviet  Union  as  super  powers.  Both  extend  over 
large  continental  areas  and  both  have  expanded  beyond  these  boundaries. 
The  forms  of  these  expansions  are  manifold.  As  in  the  case  of  the  Soviet 
satellites,  they  may  have  taken  shape  by  forcing  smaller  states  to  accept 
the  leadership  of  the  super  state  in  a  manner  differing  only  to  a  small 
degree  from  outright  subjugation.  In  contrast,  the  acquisition  of  military 
bases  overseas  plays  an  important  role  in  the  security  situation  in  which 


38  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

the  United  States  finds  itself.  This  is  an  unimportant  form  of  expansion 
in  the  Soviet  Union.12 


REGIONAL  ORGANIZATIONS 

In  the  face  of  the  power  exerted  by  super  states,  smaller  states  have 
increasingly  attempted  to  safeguard  their  independence  and  to  increase 
their  influence  by  drawing  together  in  unions,  regional  organizations,  or 
federations.  Some  of  these,  such  as  the  Pan-American  Union,  also  embrace 
one  of  the  big  states,  the  smaller  members  hoping  thereby  to  influence 
their  big  neighbor's  policies.  Other  organizations,  as  for  instance  those 
of  the  Colombo  Plan  13  or  of  the  Arab  League,  try  to  keep  out  of  the 
U.S.S.R.-United  States  disputes.  Regional  organization  of  smaller  powers 
are  not  all-inclusive,  however.  We  find  a  number  of  states  which  have 
remained  uncommitted  to  some  larger  organization,  in  each  case  for 
peculiar  reasons.  Austria,  for  instance,  was  occupied  by  four  powers  until 
1955  and  was  given  no  freedom  of  choice;  nor  can  she  join  any  organ- 
ization now  as  the  result  of  the  terms  of  the  Peace  Treaty  which  reinstated 
her  sovereignty.  Israel  cannot  join  any  organization  without  making  her 
partners  unwilling  supporters  of  Israel's  unresolved  war  with  the  Arab 
bloc.  Sweden,  Finland,  Switzerland,  and  Eire  try  to  remain  independent 
and  uncommitted  to  any  bloc.  The  vast  majority  of  states,  however,  are 
in  one  form  or  another  partners  in  some  political  grouping  of  continental 
size. 

The  significance  of  this  trend  is  not  challenged  by  the  important  fact 
that  some  of  these  supra-national  organizations  are  far  from  being  stable. 
It  is  probable  that  their  size  and  membership  will  change  rapidly  in  the 
near  future.  What  connections  will  the  Sudan  make  after  attaining  sover- 
eignty? Will  the  Gold  Coast  join  the  British  Commonwealth  as  a  do- 
minion? How  long  will  the  Union  of  South  Africa  remain  a  member  of 
that  commonwealth?  How  long  will  these  small  nations  that  are  trying 
to  maintain  a  neutral  attitude  be  able  to  pursue  that  policy?  Above  all, 
will  the  Soviet  Union  and  the  United  States  be  able  to  win  over  to  their 
power  combinations  and  to  their  causes  member  states  of  the  other  bloc? 
In  any  case,  the  emergence  of  political  bodies  of  continental  size  has  to 
be  accepted  as  permanent,  even  though  their  structures  and  the  extent 
of  their  boundaries  are  and  will  remain  subject  to  change  and  fluctuation. 

12  The  vital  role  of  the  strategic  base  net  along  the  American  perimeter  of  defense 
in  the  security  picture  of  the  United  States  is  discussed  in  detail  in  Chapter  15. 

13  See  pp.  286-290. 


SIZE  39 

CONSOLIDATING  AND  DISRUPTIVE  FACTORS  IN  THE 
EMERGENCE  OF  MODERN  STATE  SYSTEMS 

The  industrial  revolution  of  the  nineteenth  century  and  modern  colo- 
nialism have  supported  the  emergence  of  large  state  structures.  The 
British  Empire,  the  Russian  Empire  of  the  Czars,  and  the  Soviet  Union 
have  no  equals  in  size  in  the  past.  The  United  States  and  France  are  not 
far  behind.  Canada  and  Brazil  are  about  to  organize  and  penetrate  their 
wide  unoccupied  spaces  as  the  United  States  did  a  century  earlier.  Some 
states,  however— Germany,  Italy,  Yugoslavia,  Rumania— became  large 
through  the  consolidation  of  several  small  states.  Such  consolidations  are 
seldom  primarily  effected  for  the  sake  of  greater  economic  efficiency,  as 
has  often  been  the  case  in  the  industrial  field.  It  is  true  that  the  customs 
union  was  the  pacemaker  for  German  national  unity,  but  at  the  same  time 
Italy  accomplished  her  national  unity  and  still  has  not  succeeded  in  weld- 
ing her  territory  into  a  uniform  economic  unit.  The  problem  of  the  impov- 
erished south,  the  Mezzogiorno,  plagues  Italy  continuously.  In  the  unifi- 
cation of  Germany  and  Italy  and  in  some  more  recent  cases,  it  was  not 
the  consideration  of  economic  efficiency,  but  the  irrational  power  of 
modern  nationalism  which  was  the  driving  force. 

Modern  nationalism  which  has  become  effective  since  the  French 
Revolution  has  not  only  contributed  to  enlarging  the  size  of  many  political 
units,  it  has  also  been  a  disruptive  force.  This  was  the  case  in  the  nine- 
teenth century  in  Europe  and  the  same  trend  is  evident  in  the  twentieth 
century  in  other  continents.  The  breakup  of  the  Hapsburg  and  Ottoman 
empires,  of  the  Scandinavian  and  the  Dutch-Belgian  unions  is  followed 
by  that  of  India  and  the  creating  of  an  Indian  Union;  Pakistan,  Ceylon, 
Eire,  Burma,  the  Arab  states,  preferred  to  establish  themselves  as  in- 
dependent states,  though  they  had  to  forego  the  many  economic  advan- 
tages of  belonging  to  large  empires.  The  creation  of  Israel  is  another 
illustration  of  this  recent  trend  toward  national  states,  however  small.14 
It  is  still  more  significant  that  the  Soviet  Union  felt  it  necessary  to  create 
autonomous  national  states,  even  though  the  autonomy  was  in  many 
respects  only  make-believe.  Although  the  Soviet  Union  could  suppress 
these  autonomous  states,  even  as  she  has  curtailed  their  function,  to  do 
so  might  well  mean  that  she  would  deprive  herself  of  much  of  her  appeal 
to  the  colonial  nations  of  Asia  and  Africa.  A  new  organization  of  Africa 
is  in  the  making  and  it  is  possible,  if  not  likely,  that  the  large  African 

14  The  area  of  Israel  is  8,048  square  miles. 


40  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

colonial  empires  will  be  replaced  by  some  smaller  national  or  pseudo- 
national  political  bodies  before  the  twentieth  century  draws  to  an  end. 
Size  is  a  variable  factor  in  the  life  of  states  and  there  is  no  uniform 
trend  toward  larger  or  smaller  states.  There  is  no  optimal  size  for  states, 
not  in  our  time  nor  in  any  period  of  the  past.  There  have  been,  however, 
very  few  instances  when  leaders  of  nations  have  regarded  their  country 
as  being  too  large;  the  Gladstonian  Liberals  in  Great  Britain  in  the  70's 
and  80's  of  the  nineteenth  century  are  the  only  well-known  case.  Striving 
for  larger  size  is,  on  the  other  hand,  a  common  historical  phenomenon. 

TERRITORIAL  AGGRANDIZEMENT  AS  PRIZE  OF  WAR 

It  is  typical  of  the  high  value  placed  on  the  size  of  states  that  territory 
is  almost  invariably  the  prize  in  a  conflict  between  nations.  Even  in  those 
cases  in  which  a  war  broke  out  for  reasons  other  than  conquest,  or  in 
which  the  attacked  nation  won  the  victory,  the  victor  commonly  asks  for 
expansion  of  his  territory.  The  United  States  entered  the  war  with  Spain 
in  1898  because  of  the  feeling  that  the  strengthening  of  any  European 
position  in  the  Americas  would  be  intolerable,  and  not  for  reasons  of 
territorial  aggrandizement.  The  war  resulted,  however,  not  only  in  the 
temporary  occupation  of  Cuba,  but  in  the  annexation  of  Puerto  Rico  and 
even  of  the  remote  Philippines,  which  in  no  way  had  been  an  object 
of  contention.  Belgium  in  1914,  the  Netherlands  in  1941,  would  have  been 
content  to  be  left  alone  in  the  conflict  of  the  great  powers;  nevertheless, 
at  the  end  of  the  World  Wars,  they  demanded,  and  obtained,  territory 
from  defeated  Germany.  In  many  cases  such  demands  are  disguised  as 
compensation  for  damages  suffered.  The  case  of  Bismarck  who,  after 
Prussia  had  won  the  war  of  1866,  persuaded  the  King  of  Prussia  to 
conclude  a  peace  treaty  with  Austria  without  territorial  cessions  (in 
order  to  insure  Austrian  neutrality  in  the  coming  conflict  with  France) 
is  a  rare  exception  to  this  general  rule.  In  a  power  bloc  as  large  as  the 
Soviet  orbit  which  includes  many  contending  nationalities,  we  find  such 
internal  territorial  changes  benefiting  one  partner  at  the  cost  of  another. 
The  Ukrainian  Republic  within  the  U.S.S.R.  has  a  total  area  of  232,625 
square  miles,  of  which  not  less  than  25  per  cent  was  acquired  after  World 
War  II  from  Soviet  satellites:  Eastern  Galicia,  34,700  square  miles,  from 
Poland;  Subcarpathian  Ruthenia,  5,000  square  miles,  from  Czechoslo- 
vakia; Northern  Bukovina  and  part  of  Bessarabia,  8,000  square  miles, 
from  Rumania.  In  February,  1954,  the  Crimean  peninsula  ( 10,000  square 
miles)  which  had  lost  its  autonomous  status  at  the  end  of  World  War  II 


SIZE 


41 


77777a ? 

■belorussian  s.s.r. 


2 

*& 


Fig.  2-4.  The  Ukrainian  S.S.R.  (1955):  (1)  present  Ukrainian  territory;  (2)  pre- 
World  War  II  Rumania;  (3)  pre-World  War  II  Czechoslovakia;  (4)  pre- World 
War  II  Poland. 

because  of  the  alleged  co-operation  of  its  people  with  the  Germans,  was 
incorporated  into  the  Ukrainian  Republic  (Fig.  2-4). 

An  important  motivating  power  for  territorial  aggrandizement  is  the 
prestige  with  which  size  endows  a  country.  The  mere  fact  of  size  gives 
to  a  state  a  certain  standing  in  the  community  of  nations.  The  occupation 
of  the  western  Sahara  by  Spain,  or  the  claims  of  Chile,  Argentina,  and 
other  countries  to  Antarctic  wastes,  spring  partly  from  this  source.  If 
the  large  state  is  united  in  one  continuous  territory,  this  factor  gives  to 
its  citizens  a  feeling  of  security  and  importance.  Being  removed  from 
contact  with  other  nations,  a  deceptive  feeling  of  independence,  protec- 
tion, and  security  develops,  especially  among  persons  who  live  in  the 
interior.  Out  of  this  feeling  grows  a  powerful  concept  of  "splendid  iso- 
lation" which  clearly  has  its  roots  in  geographical  ignorance. 


THE  MAP  AS  A  CAUSE  OF  GEOGRAPHICAL  MISCONCEPTIONS 

A  contributing  factor  to  the  growth  and  survival  of  these  geographical 
misconceptions  is  the  map:  the  average  school  atlas  depicts  a  student's 
own  country,  his  own  continent,  in  larger  scale  than  other  countries  and 


42 


THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 


. 1> 

\ 


( 


100 

I — 


200 
i 


300  Mi 


100      200      300  Km 


J.R.F. 


Fig.  2-5.  Comparative  Size  of  France  ( superimposed  on  Minnesota,  Iowa,  and 

Wisconsin ) . 

continents.  Independent  countries  are  given  more  prominence  than  even 
large  constituent  parts  of  still  larger  states.  Many  people  have  the  im- 
pression that  France  is  a  very  large  country,  while  actually  it  is  about 
the  size  of  Minnesota,  Wisconsin,  and  Iowa  combined  (Fig.  2-5).  On 
most  maps  showing  individual  continents,  Europe  is  presented  in  larger 
scale  than  Asia,  although  non-Soviet  Europe  is  only  slightly  larger  than 
India  ( Fig.  2-6 ) .  It  is  seldom  realized  that  Brazil  with  its  3,288,000  square 
miles  is  larger  than  the  2,977,000  square  miles  of  the  United  States,  and 
that  both  together  are  still  much  smaller  than  the  Soviet  Union  ( 8,700,000 
square  miles).  (See  Fig.  2-7.) 

This  reference  to  the  map  as  a  primary  cause  of  common  misconceptions 
of  size  factors  would  be  incomplete  without  mentioning  the  misuse  of 
the  (in  many  respects  extremely  valuable)  Mercator  projection  as  largely 


SIZE 


43 


Fig.  2-6.  India  and  Europe  at  the  Same  Scale. 


responsible  for  such  errors.  Although  it  shows  true  compass  directions 
and  therefore  is  still  the  ideal  map  for  ship  navigators,  the  Mercator  map 
has  serious  shortcomings.  Except  in  the  vicinity  of  the  Equator,  it  does 
not  even  pretend  to  show  the  correct  relative  size  of  the  land  areas  of 
the  globe.  The  nearer  one  comes  to  the  North  Pole,  or  to  the  South  Pole, 
the  more  distorted  are  the  factors  of  size  as  shown  on  the  Mercator  map.15 
Richard  E.  Harrison,  with  European  geographers,  has  called  attention  to 
the  elementary,  yet  to  most  of  us  surprising  fact  that  on  a  Mercator  world 
map  Greenland  appears  larger  than  the  continent  of  South  America.  But 
when  shown  in  its  true  relative  size,  we  discover  that  it  is  only  about  one 
tenth  of  the  area  of  South  America.  An  even  better  example  (Fig.  2-8)  is 
offered  by  Ellesmere  Island,  northwest  of  Greenland.  On  a  Mercator 
world  map  with  its  typical  distortions  in  the  polar  regions  Ellesmere 
Island  appears  to  be  almost  as  large  as  Australia.  Actually,  when  it  is 

15  R.  E.  Harrison,  Maps,  2nd  ed.  (Consolidated  Vultee  Aircraft  Corporation,  1943), 
p.  7;  R.  E.  Harrison  and  H.  W.  Weigert,  "World  View  and  Strategy,"  in  H.  W.  Weigert 
and  V.  Stefansson,  eds.,  Compass  of  the  World  (New  York,  1945),  pp.  74-88. 


44 


THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 


J.&.F. 


Fig.  2-7.  Comparative  Size  of  U.S.S.R.,  United  States,  and  Brazil. 

shown  beside  Australia  in  its  true  relative  dimensions,  Ellesmere  Island 
dwindles  to  dwarf  size  (Fig.  2-8). 


THE  VALUE  OF  SIZE  AS  A  SECURITY.  FACTOR 

It  is  obvious  that  size  is  an  important  factor  in  the  determination  of 
economic  and  political  power.  However,  whether  it  evolves  as  an  asset 
or  as  a  liability  depends  on  many  factors.  In  a  general  way,  it  can  be 
stated  that  size  tends  to  be  an  asset  to  military  power.  Only  a  large 
country,  such  as  the  Soviet  Union  in  World  War  II,  can  trade  space  for 
time  and  win,  after  retreating— voluntarily  or  by  necessity— for  hundreds 
of  miles.  The  time  needed  for  the  enemy's  advance  is  used  to  build  up 
new  industries,  to  train  new  troops,  and  to  prepare  a  counteroffensive. 
Only  in  very  large  countries  can  areas  still  be  found  which  are  sufficiently 
remote  from  enemy  bases  to  be  relatively  safe  from  air  attack.  Only  in 
a  large  territory  can  an  air  raid  warning  system  function  efficiently.  On 
the  other  hand,  large  size,  coupled  with  other  factors,  can  pose  serious 
problems  to  military  strategy;  for  instance,  outlying  parts  of  a  large 
country,  if  thinly  populated  and  if  lacking  adequate  communications  lines, 
are  difficult  to  defend— a  problem  Russia  experienced  in  the  war  with 
Japan  in  1904  to  1905.  For  similar  reasons,  the  defense  of  Alaska  is  a 
problem  to  military  planning  in  the  United  States. 


SIZE 


45 


MERCATOR 


GREENLAND 


TRUE 

COMPARATIVE 

SIZE 


ELLESMERE  I 


ELLESMERE  I. 


m 


Fig.  2-8.  Effects  of  Projections  on  Appearance  of  Size:  Greenland,  South  America, 
Ellesmere  Island,  Australia  (after  R.  E.  Harrison). 

In  a  country  of  small  size,  this  factor  always  is  negative  if  contemplated 
in  terms  of  external  security.  If  invaded,  even  if  ultimately  on  the  winning 
side,  the  small  country  will  suffer  damages  affecting  its  entire  territory, 
whereas  a  large  country,  even  if  forced  to  accept  defeat,  may  still  retain 
large  areas  untouched  by  the  direct  effects  of  war. 

We  must  always  be  aware  that  evaluations  of  size  factors  with  reference 
to  military  planning  and  security  can  not  lead  to  more  than  observations 
of  a  very  general  nature.  This  note  of  caution  has  never  been  more  timely 
than  in  our  age  of  potential  hydrogen  bomb  warfare.  The  development 
of  thermonuclear  weapons,  and  the  problem  of  radioactive  "fall-out, '  have 
shattered  our  concepts  of  security.  In  a  territory  of  small  size,  there  will 
no  longer  be  left  any  areas  of  refuge  or  safety.  But  even  for  areas  of  larger 


46  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

size,  spatial  factors  such  as  remoteness  and  depth  have  lost  much  of  their 
meaning.  The  horrifying  effects  of  nuclear  warfare  make  it  imperative 
to  reappraise  the  size  factor  wherever,  in  yesterday's  thinking,  it  appeared 
to  be  an  asset  to  the  defense  position  of  a  nation. 

EFFECTS  OF  SIZE  ON  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION, 
ECONOMIC  POWER 

There  is  a  relationship  between  the  size  of  a  country  and  the  costs  and 
management  of  its  public  administration.  A  large  country  will  have  to 
spend  relatively  less  for  all  centralized  services,  such  as  the  administration 
of  foreign  relations,  legislation,  and  the  administration  of  justice.  A  large 
country  may  also  have  more  diversified  natural  resources  within  its  bound- 
aries, thereby  reducing  its  dependency  on  other  nations.  The  larger  a 
country  the  better  are  its  chances  of  approximating  self-sufficiency.  In 
the  actual  conditions  of  present-day  nations  there  are,  however,  important 
exceptions  to  this  general  rule.  Spain  and  Czechoslovakia  have  more,  and 
more  diversified,  natural  resources  than  many  countries  of  much  larger 
size;  Italy  and  Norway  have  fewer  than  other  countries  of  smaller  size. 
Luxembourg,  a  dwarf  state  if  measured  by  size  alone,  has  no  great  diver- 
sity of  natural  resources,  but  its  wealth  of  coal  and  iron,  two  of  the 
modern  key  resources,  make  it  a  valued  partner  in  the  Benelux  Union 
and  a  by  no  means  negligible  factor  in  West  European  power  politics  in 
peace  times.  In  war  its  small  size  prevents  it  from  playing  a  significant 
role,  even  as  an  ally  of  some  other  power. 

SIZE  AND  POPULATION 

The  most  important  factor  tending  to  offset  the  importance  of  mere 
size  is  population.  A  thinly  populated,  sprawling  country  is  handicapped 
by  the  necessity  of  maintaining  costly  transportation  organizations; 
whereas  efficiency  is  easily  attained  by  much  smaller  countries  having 
similar  population  figures.  On  the  other  hand,  the  needs  of  a  large  pop- 
ulation may  tax  too  heavily  the  resources  of  a  country  and  weaken  its 
influence  among  the  nations  of  the  world.  Only  in  this  case  would  we 
speak  of  overpopulation.  India  and  Egypt  are  cases  in  point.  Densely 
populated  Belgium  is,  without  its  colonial  empire,  a  small  country  of 
12,000  square  miles,  but  it  is  culturally,  economically,  and  even  militarily 
of  much  greater  importance  than,  for  instance,  larger  Austria   (32,375 


SIZE  47 

square  miles)  or  Bulgaria  (42,796  square  miles).  That  Ethiopia,  a  country 
one  and  a  half  times  the  size  of  France,  is  of  almost  negligible  influence 
and  power,  is  due  not  only  to  the  scarcity  of  its  population  of  11  million 
but  also  to  its  relative  cultural  backwardness.  Cultural  and  technological 
underdevelopment  are  factors  which  can  hardly  be  measured,  but  their 
influence  can  nevertheless  offset  completely  the  influence  of  large  size. 

Apart  from  the  actual  numbers  of  people,  their  distribution  within  a 
state  is  of  decisive  importance.  A  striking  example  is  Canada  which  has 
areas  of  relatively  dense  population  but  also  other  extensive  areas  which 
are  for  all  practical  purposes  uninhabited.  Not  the  map  picturing  the  size 
of  Canada  but  one  showing  the  distribution  and  density  of  its  population 
of  14,000,000  explains  its  political  geography  (Fig.  2-9).  This  shows 
clearly  that  Canada's  settled  areas  are  along  the  southern,  American 
border,  and  that  they  are  separated  into  two  groups  by  the  large  un- 
inhabited Laurentian  wilderness.  Each  of  these  groups  is  divided  again 
into  two  areas  of  dense  population,  separated  in  the  western  provinces 
by  the  thinly  populated  areas  of  the  Canadian  Rocky  mountains,  and  in 
the  eastern  provinces  by  the  thinly  settled  hill  country  of  southeastern 
Quebec.  Nevertheless,  it  would  be  erroneous  to  think  of  Canada  as  a 
group  of  four  loosely  connected  areas  strung  out  north  of  the  42°  parallel. 
The  unpeopled  spaces  between  the  populated  areas  are  like  the  tissues 
in  the  human  body  between  the  vital  organs.  Frequently  the  sparsely 
settled  areas  have  yielded  unexpected  natural  resources  and  have  thus 
offered  new  possibilities  of  development.  A  Canada  without  its  hold  over 
these  spaces  would  not  reach  the  Arctic  Ocean  except  at  a  few  points, 
its  role  among  the  world  powers  would  be  altogether  different. 

Similar  conditions  exist  in  other  areas.  The  Australian  Commonwealth 
(Fig.  2-10),  if  it  included  only  the  well-settled  coastal  areas  would  be 
only  a  number  of  barely  connected,  hardly  defensible  small  settlements. 
Australia  is  at  present  a  rather  influential  power  because  of  its  continental 
size  (2,975,000  square  miles),  despite  its  small  population.  Comparable 
in  population  ( 8,500,000  in  1951 )  as  well  as  in  cultural  and  technological 
development  to  Belgium  (8,700,000  in  1951),  its  size  among  other  factors 
gives  it  a  different  weight  in  international  affairs.  As  in  the  case  of 
Canada,  the  recent  discovery  of  mineral  resources  ( in  particular  uranium 
and  oil),  in  hitherto  "empty  spaces,"  has  had  a  profound  effect  on  Aus- 
tralia's internal  and  external  political  geography. 

Among  the  major  regions  of  "empty  spaces"  the  Sahara  with  an  area 
of  over  three  million  square  miles  is  certainly  as  much  an  anecumene  as 


W2 

u 
<U 

T3 

C 
9 


to 


© 

Ifi 

I 

in 


m 


© 

© 


© 


© 
in 

i 

© 
© 


w 


© 
© 
in 

i 

© 
in 


© 
© 

m 

■- 

> 

o 


s- 
« 

CO 

hi 

a 


s 
Q 

o 


a 

o 

« 

« 

s 

M 

o 

cp 

U 


48 


SIZE 


49 


:.:Sf  *  y . 


INDONESIAN   REPUBLIC 


110 

■  1 


120 


130 


1 45 
„L_ 


\  TASMANIA 

\^jf'        150 


Til 


Fig.  2-10.  Australia  (Continental  Shelf:  unshaded  water  portion). 

is  the  ocean.  However,  without  its  firm  grip  on  the  Sahara  the  French 
African  colonial  empire  would  lose  much  of  its  compactness  and  defen- 
sibility. 

The  political  map  may  grossly  mislead  the  unwary  by  showing  size 
without  the  necessary  qualifications.  Political  geography  cannot  rely  on 
the  political  map  alone;  the  physiographic  map,  presenting  deserts,  moun- 
tains, swamps,  virgin  forests,  lakes,  and  large  rivers  has  to  furnish  the 
necessary  qualifications  and  limitations  for  the  evaluation  of  size;  the 
population  maps  and  maps  of  resources  are  other  indispensable  adjuncts. 
Location,  another  limiting  factor,  will  be  discussed  in  another  chapter 
in  more  detail. 


THE  RISKS  OF  OVEREXPANSION 


It  is  obvious  that  small  countries  are  susceptible  to  pressure  from  large 
and  powerful  nations,  but  the  size  of  large  nations  does  not  exempt  them 
from  pressure.  It  is  less  obvious,  perhaps,  but  large  size  itself  entails 


50  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

certain  weaknesses.  Countries  in  the  process  of  vastly  expanding  their 
territories  will  eventually  enclose  national  groups  which  cannot  be  recon- 
ciled with  their  absorption  into  the  large  states.  Whether  this  is  a  national 
minority  problem  in  the  modern  sense,  or  the  stage  for  the  rebellion  of 
an  ambitious  satrap,  as  happened  so  often  in  the  old  empires  on  Indian 
and  Iranian  soil,  is  of  little  importance  in  this  connection.  In  former  times, 
due  to  slow  and  undeveloped  communications,  the  cultural  influence  and 
the  power  of  the  core  area  (as  for  instance  Latium  in  the  center  of  the 
Roman  Empire)  diminished  the  farther  away  from  the  center  a  province 
was  located.  But  even  today  the  interests  of  a  dominant  central  province 
may  lead  to  the  neglect  of  divergent  interests  of  marginal  provinces.  The 
Iberian  peninsula  is  a  case  in  point.  Here  the  maritime,  commercial,  and 
industrial  interests  of  Catalonia,  Asturia,  and  the  Vascongadas  have  been 
neglected  by  a  central  government  which  is  dominated  by  the  land-locked 
vision  and  the  agricultural  interests  of  the  Castilians  of  the  interior.  In  the 
British  Empire  not  only  subject  colonial  people  strive  for  independence, 
but  peripheral  English-speaking  areas  aim  at  increasing  their  independ- 
ence as  dominions  or  as  loosely  federated  partners  of  equal  standing. 

Owen  Lattimore  has  shown  16  that  Chinese  expansion  finally  reached 
a  zone  of  diminishing  returns,  where  people  could  no  longer  be  converted 
to  the  Chinese  way  of  life— to  adopt  the  language,  houses,  and  social 
system  of  the  conquerors— primarily  because  the  adoption  of  Chinese 
agricultural  methods  in  arid  areas  proved  unprofitable.  There  was  even 
a  strong  incentive,  in  these  areas,  for  the  Chinese  immigrant  to  become  a 
herdsman  and  to  become  "barbarized"  by  accepting  the  way  of  life  which 
went  with  nomadic  herding.  As  a  result,  Chinese  political  rule  in  such 
areas  did  not  last  long.  Lattimore  also  traced  a  corresponding  limiting 
trend  for  the  Russian  expansion  in  Inner  Asia. 


PSYCHOLOGICAL  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS  RELATED  TO  SIZE 

Large  countries  breed  often  a  mental  attitude  which  is  inimical  to  an 
understanding  of  foreigners  and  may  ultimately  lead  to  fatal  mistakes  in 
dealing  with  other  nations.  It  is  not  necessarily  narrow-mindedness  and 
stress  of  the  particular  local  interests,  it  is  a  geographically  induced  and 
unavoidable  lack  of  ability  to  understand  others.  Even  in  the  shrinking 

16  O.  Lattimore,  "The  New  Political  Geography  of  Inner  Asia,"  Geographical 
Journal,  Vol.  119  (March,  1953),  and  more  in  detail  for  the  Chinese,  Inner  Asian 
Frontiers  of  China,  American  Geographical-Sociological  Research  Series,  No.  21,  1940. 


SIZE  51 

world  of  today  it  holds  true  that  part  of  the  population  never  has  the 
opportunity  to  come  in  contact  with  foreigners,  or  only  with  a  few 
individuals.  The  mass  of  the  population,  therefore,  do  not  develop  real 
understanding  of  foreign  thinking  and  attitudes.  Strange  as  it  may  appear, 
the  larger  a  country,  the  less  diversified  tend  to  be  its  foreign  contacts. 
The  United  States  is  an  extreme  example,  with  only  two  countries  as 
direct  neighbors.  The  number  of  Americans  who  are  continuously  aware 
of  conditions  in  a  foreign  country,  even  of  Mexico  or  Canada,  is  very 
small.  Both  these  countries  are  sorely  neglected  in  most  of  the  textbooks 
on  American  history  used  in  American  schools  and  the  small  space  and 
time  allowed  to  matters  Canadian  or  Mexican  in  the  average  local  news- 
paper or  radio  station  illustrates  the  lack  of  interest,  in  the  United  States, 
in  the  affairs  of  the  two  neighboring  nations.  However,  radio  and  tele- 
vision and  especially  the  fact  that  millions  of  Americans  have  served 
overseas  during  and  since  the  war  have  prompted  a  greater  awareness  of, 
and  interest  in,  foreign  affairs. 

In  contrast,  Switzerland  borders  on  four  countries,  Hungary  on  five, 
while  the  U.S.S.R.  borders  on  nine,  and  the  British  Empire  through  its 
colonies  on  many  more.  There  is  hardly  a  Swiss  or  Hungarian  who  is  not 
aware  in  one  way  or  another  of  happenings  in  two  or  even  three  foreign 
countries.  There  are  none  who  live  farther  away  from  a  foreign  country 
than  sixty-five  miles.  Cultural  interaction  is  pronounced,  knowledge  of 
foreign  languages— the  best  means  of  cultural  contact— much  more  wide- 
spread than  in  the  United  States.  Thus  we  find  that  lack  of  cultural 
contacts,  as  a  natural  consequence  of  the  large  size  of  a  country,  causes 
the  outlook  of  its  citizens  to  be  often  more  parochial  than  is  true  in 
countries  of  small  size.  Again  this  general  observation  is  not  without 
exception. 

An  oddly  similar  parochial  outlook  exists  in  many  small  countries  where 
the  citizens  live  under  the  illusion  that  their  co-nationals  have  done  more 
than  their  share  for  world  civilization.  It  is  a  distorted  perspective  which 
sees  things  close  to  home  as  much  larger  than  remote  ones.  Most  history 
books  of  small  countries  depict  national  inventors,  artists,  and  writers  as 
people  of  international  fame,  while  actually  their  contributions  may  be 
unknown  abroad. 

In  internal  politics  the  size  factor  has  important  ramifications,  especially 
in  large  countries  where  the  normal  concentration  of  political  activities  in 
the  capital  usually  results  also  in  drawing  most  of  a  country's  cultural 
activities  toward  the  political  center.  Such  concentration  is  apt  to  promote 
the  development  of  a  provincial,  if  not  backward,  outlook  among  the 


52  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

population  in  regions  remote  from  the  cultural  and  political  nucleus. 
Sometimes  we  find,  as  a  usually  healthy  reaction,  the  growth  of  several 
and  competing  cultural  centers.  Again  the  size  of  the  country  is  a  sig- 
nificant conditioning  factor  in  this  process.  The  multiplicity  of  cultural 
centers  in  the  numerous  capitals  of  politically  divided  Germany  in  the 
fifteenth  to  eighteenth  centuries,  in  Italy  from  the  thirteenth  to  the  eight- 
eenth century,  or  in  the  many  states  of  India  at  several  periods,  as  com- 
pared with  the  overwhelming  concentration  of  intellectual,  artistic,  and 
scientific  activity  in  Paris,  Madrid,  Peking,  or  Tokyo  are  illustrations. 
A  modern  example  of  a  deliberate  attempt  to  avoid  what  was  considered 
undesirable  political  and  cultural  concentration  in  one  capital  is  the  Union 
of  South  Africa.  South  Africa  has  two  capitals,  the  legislative  in  Cape 
Town,  and  the  administrative  in  Pretoria.  Even  in  a  federal  state  like 
the  United  States,  cities  such  as  New  York,  Washington,  Boston,  and 
a  few  others  tend  to  draw  all  cultural  activities  into  their  orbit.  A 
French  geographer,  Jean  Gottman,  observed  that  an  American  "mega- 
polis,"  four  hundred  miles  long  and  populated  by  thirty  million  persons 
in  not  more  than  a  half-dozen  states,  influences  thinking,  fashions, 
manner  of  speech,  and  social  relations,  as  well  as  political  concepts. 
"Although  dependent  upon  the  rest  of  the  nation  for  food  and  communi- 
cation, this  megapolis  is  becoming  an  area  'outside'  of  the  United  States, 
just  as  Amsterdam,  Naples,  Rome,  and  to  a  degree,  London  and  Paris 
are  entities."  1T 

SIZE  FACTORS  IN  INTERNAL  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

Large  or  small  size  of  a  country  plays  an  important  role  in  shaping  a 
country's  internal  political  geography,  especially  in  regard  to  internal 
divisions  of  states.  When  the  French  Revolution  abolished  the  historical 
provinces,  and  organized  rational,  but  artificial  administrative  subdivisions 
(departments),  it  was  decided  that  the  size  of  each  unit  should  be 
determined  by  the  consideration  that  each  citizen  should  be  able  to  visit 
the  seat  of  the  administration  and  to  return  to  his  home  on  the  same  day, 
after  having  attended  to  his  business.  The  development  of  modern  com- 
munication forms  has  since  rendered  this  basis  for  the  size  of  the  depart- 
ments meaningless.  That  they  have  survived,  and  that  France's  internal 
political  geography  is  still  basically  unchanged,  shows  how  well  these 
units  became  established  in  French  life.  Ratzel  in  his  time  stressed  the 
point  that  it  is  much  easier  to  change  internal  borders  than  international 

17  New  York  Times,  January  25,  1953. 


SIZE  53 

ones,  and  gave  a  great  number  of  examples.18  It  seems  remarkable,  there- 
fore, how  seldom  such  changes  of  interior  boundaries  occur,  and  then 
usually  only  under  revolutionary  or  other  unsettled  conditions.  In  France, 
after  World  War  II,  when  everything  seemed  unsettled,  it  was  decided 
to  replace  these  departments  by  larger  administrative  units,  more  in  tune 
with  technological  advances  and  the  need  for  larger  economic  grouping. 
However,  before  action  was  taken,  life  had  reverted  largely  to  the  accus- 
tomed ruts  and  nothing  was  done. 

It  can  be  observed  that  within  states  subdivisions  tend  to  be  larger 
the  thinner  the  population  is  spread.  The  western  provinces  of  Canada, 
the  northeastern  subdivisions  of  the  U.S.S.R.,  the  southern  regions  of 
Algeria,  are  some  of  the  best  known  examples.  Such  large  subdivisions 
are  characteristic  of  areas  that  lacked  a  dense  indigenous  population  in 
the  first  stages  of  colonization.  The  western  states  of  the  United  States 
were  carved  out  of  immense  territories,  such  as  the  Northwest  Territory 
and  the  Kansas  Territory.  In  Brazil,  a  similar  administrative  pattern  of 
more  recent  date  is  evident,  following  the  progress  of  colonization.  In  the 
normal  trend  of  consolidation,  boundaries,  local  loyalties,  and  the  pattern 
of  administration  become  crystallized  and  no  further  subdivisions  take 
place,  or  they  occur  only  under  extraordinary  conditions,  as  in  the  sepa- 
ration of  West  Virginia  from  Virginia  during  the  Civil  War  when  these 
two  states  adhered  to  the  Union  and  to  the  Confederacy  respectively. 
Size  as  such  is  no  sufficient  motive  to  prompt  the  breaking-up  of  admin- 
istrative units.  Neither  California  nor  Texas  are  expected  to  split  into  two 
or  more  states  because  of  the  large  size  of  their  territories.  Thus  the 
different  size  of  subdivisions  bears  and  maintains  the  imprint  of  con- 
ditions which  prevailed  when  they  were  formed  or  which  shaped  them 
during  a  revolutionary  period.  The  formative  influence  may  have  been 
that  of  railroads  as  when  the  mountain  states  were  formed  or  that  of 
carts  and  pack  animals  as  when  the  New  England  states  were  colonized. 
The  need  for  defense  against  sudden  attacks  across  borders  accounts  for 
the  creation  of  marches,  that  is,  larger  territorial  units  than  the  usual 
units  such  as  counties  or  dukedoms.  Relics  of  such  medieval  marches  in 
England  are  the  large  counties  along  the  Scottish  and  Welsh  borders; 
similar  marches  existed  in  Eastern  Germany,  and  survived  as  large  polit- 
ical subdivisions  to  the  end  of  World  War  II.  They  are  the  historical  basis 
of  the  independent  state  of  Austria. 

Smaller  political  subdivisions  are,  generally,  easier  to  change  than  large 

18  F.  Ratzel,  Politische  Geographie,  3rd  ed.  (Munich,  1920). 


54  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

ones.  They  command  fewer  emotional  loyalties  and  in  many  states  their 
functions  are  not  important.  As  a  rule,  it  has  been  easier  to  create  new 
counties  than  to  change  state  boundaries.  It  is  true  that  local  loyalties 
exist  also  in  counties,  but  they  exert  influence  only  when  they  coincide 
with  material  benefits.19  With  the  development  of  modern  communica- 
tions these  cases  have  become  rather  infrequent. 

On  the  other  hand,  larger  units  have  increasingly  come  into  being 
because  they  alone  were  able  to  cope  efficiently  with  the  complicated 
problems  of  modern  economic  life.  The  Tennessee  Valley  Authority  is 
perhaps  the  best-known  example  of  a  large  territorial  unit  created  without 
replacing  traditional  state  boundaries.  The  New  York  Port  Authority  is 
another  example.  In  the  international  field  the  Caribbean  Commission 
is  one  of  several  examples.  It  unites  American,  British,  French,  and  Dutch 
possessions  for  explicitly  defined  social,  economic,  and  cultural  purposes. 

None  of  these  examples  proves  convincingly  that  there  is  a  trend 
toward  larger  administrative  units.  In  the  Soviet  Union  the  Communists 
replaced  the  large  administrative  divisions,  the  gubernivas  and  their 
subdivisions,  the  volosts,  by  oblasts  and  rayons.  Industrialization  and 
the  increased  need  for  political  and  economic  administration  and  control 
led  to  a  decrease  in  the  size  of  these  new  subdivisions  as  compared 
with  the  subdivisions  of  Czarist  Russia.  This  is  another  example  showing 
how  a  revolution  can  overthrow  traditional  forms  no  longer  fitted  to 
modern  conditions.  While  in  the  first  decade  of  the  Soviet  state  the 
boundaries  of  these  oblasts  and  volosts  remained  flexible,  the  number 
of  such  transformations  shows  a  decreasing  trend  as  the  U.S.S.R.  acquires 
traditional  values  of  its  own. 

Contradictory  tendencies  toward  increasing  and  decreasing  size  can 
even  be  observed  in  the  size  of  cities,  despite  the  undeniable  world-wide 
trends  toward  urbanization.  Only  a  few  years  ago  there  seemed  to  be 
no  question  that  cities  were  growing  and  that  incorporation  both  of  for- 
merly rural  areas  and  adjoining  cities  constituted  a  general  and  inevitable 
trend.  Where  older  communities  retained  their  separate  existence,  even  if 
surrounded  by  a  growing  metropolitan  area  ( such  as  Highland  Park  and 
Hamtramck  in  Detroit  (Fig.  2-11),  or  Brookline  in  Boston),  this  was  re- 
garded as  a  temporary  delay,  which  could  be  explained  by  special  socio- 
logical factors.  Even  the  actual  shrinking  of  some  cities  by  war  destruc- 
tion, as  in  Germany,  or  by  revolutionary  change,  as  in  the  case  of  Vienna 

19  Changes  of  voting  districts,  the  so-called  gerrymandering,  does  not  quite  belong 
in  this  category,  as  in  many  ways  voting  districts  do  not  have  a  separate  life  or  any 
function  except  during  election  time. 


SIZE 


55 


g 

sa  — 


■     ■      ■       

tr  r  ~7rr"'r?rr'""Trr  rprrVT?  ~. 
Ir-rTrTr-rr-ri-rrrrrrrrrTri 
Irrrrrr  r-err <~ r  r rrrr rr r  p i 

Irrrrrrrrrrrprrff  rr  rn 
r~»"f"rT*!"r-r,:"f*  :••(-  i-rrrr-pi-prj 
jrrTPr  rf  rrrrrrT-rrrr: 
[rprrrrrrp  rrrf  r*P  ■"'■  ••-'•'- 
Irir*  r  r*  r 

Bfrr 

::  I  r  r  r  •"  r  r  r  p  r  p  r  r  ■■■•  r :~  r  r  r  p  r  r  r  p  r 


-p  rr  rrrrr; 


HIGHLAND  PARKl 


HAMTRAMCKipjlilEiljltiiylipi 
•:!liLi'"pf"  ppprPrf'i"Pi"pi"p  rirrrrrrr  rrrrrr  -!^tf^'  '"<"■'  rrrr  rrr rrrr  «^:;;j[j:jj:::j| 
"  illlHI  I  ■  r  r  P  ■•■  P  — U  '•  r  ruMi  i"  P  ~Om'  r  r  ^zLr  r  r  r  P*if  rrr  r-jJ-  rrr  »ta«  rrrrrrrr  rViiiliiillLi^"  -J> 


-jjjjjjj^.rrr-' 


::::::::::::::::::::." ■  >  ~ Zf^~~'  J "ji-1  -,-,-TT'  I  u^-^Ui-. 

"j™"jjj.:jjljrjjjj.!>f!"rrrrrrrrri 


jVrrrrr'rrrrr 
j.Vrr-rrpr 

u:— ^^^^ ,^..^_ ,jjjjjjj.jprrrrr 

Si-: I j _' j _■_!_;_;-.; jjj.!/aVij  'Jjjj.rrrrrrrr 


l'jd±'l?5AJi?9il.y.jdJdJdX-rrrr 


V/>A>  WINDSOR  irA/i 


Fig.  2-11.  Encircling  Growth  of  Metropolitan  Area:  Detroit. 


which  lost  its  position  as  the  capital  of  a  great  power,  seemed  not  to  con- 
tradict the  general  trend.  This  belonged  in  the  same  category  as  the 
destruction  of  Pompeii  and  St.  Pierre  by  volcanoes,  of  Yokohama  by  earth- 
quake. Only  recently,  and  especially  pronounced  in  England  after  the  de- 
struction caused  by  World  War  II,  the  construction  of  satellite  towns 
around  metropolitan  agglomerations  has  set  in.  In  most  other  countries 
such  a  tendency  is  still  in  the  discussion  stage.  However,  we  witness  in  the 
United  States  a  novel  and  recent  trend  by  which  suburbs  are  developing 
their  own  community  life.  Distance  from  the  city  centers,  overcrowding  of 
public  transportation,  lack  of  parking  space,  and  so  on,  are  the  tangible 
causes.  The  development  of  suburban  shopping  centers  and  cultural  facil- 
ities leads  to  the  gradual  transformation  of  "dormitory  towns"  into  com- 
munities fulfilling  all  administrative  and  sociological  functions  of  the 
cities.  It  is  interesting  to  observe  that,  while  this  development  goes  on, 
larger  territorial  units  are  created  for  certain  functions  better  served  on  a 
broad  metropolitan  basis.  Such  functions  may  be  public  services,  as  tele- 
phone, water,  sewage,  fuel  distribution,  or  sanitary  provisions.  The  United 
States'  Census  recognized  the  latter  development  in  1950  by  establishing 
metropolitan  areas  and  thus  supplementing  the  census  data  usually  ob- 
tained only  along  lines  of  incorporated  city  limits. 


56  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

PHYSIOGRAPHIC  FACTORS  IN  THEIR  INFLUENCE  ON  THE 
SIZE  OF  POLITICAL  UNITS 

At  first  German  geographers  and  later  those  of  other  nationalities 
elaborated  on  the  idea  that  the  size  of  states  is  largely  conditioned  by 
their  geographical  environment.  On  extensive  plains  without  natural  bar- 
riers large  empires  have  developed.  They  have  mushroomed  in  this  en- 
vironment with  surprising  rapidity;  they  have  also  been  shortlived  in 
many  instances.  Clearly  it  is  easy  to  conquer  large,  uniform  plains;  it 
may  also  be  easy  to  organize  such  uniform  spaces,  although  this  statement 
requires  qualification.  It  is  by  no  means  certain  that  such  plains  will 
eventually  be  consolidated  in  large  states.  The  East  European  plain  and 
the  Indo-Gangetic  plain  have  not  only  seen  the  Russian,  the  Maurya, 
and  the  Mogul  Empires,  but  also  centuries  of  political  division.  The 
plains  of  the  Sudan  and  of  Inner  Asia  have  supported  large  empires 
during  relatively  short  periods  only.  No  such  empire  has  ever  arisen  in 
the  Mississippi  lowland.  In  the  case  of  the  Aztec  state  of  Mexico,  and 
of  the  Inca  empire,  high  plateaus  substituted  for  plains.  The  Roman  and 
the  Persian  Empires  are  instances  of  large  and  long-lasting  empires  which 
did  not  develop  around  nuclei  of  large  plains. 

There  are  regions,  especially  in  mountains  and  on  islands,  where  small 
natural  units  such  as  valleys  or  basins  tend  to  provide  a  good  frame  for 
small  political  units.  These  may  be  political  units  -of  secondary  impor- 
tance, such  as  the  minute  cantons  of  Switzerland,  twenty-two  of  which 
co-exist  in  an  area  not  larger  than  Massachusetts  and  New  Hampshire 
combined.  Or  these  units  may  be  independent  countries,  such  as  the 
small  states  of  the  Himalayas,  the  Alps,  or  formerly  of  the  Caucasus. 
Large  conquering  nations  from  the  surrounding  lowlands  have  been  able 
occasionally  to  conquer  these  mountains,  but  the  periods  when  these 
mountains  belonged  to  large  states  were  short  in  comparison  with  their 
long  histories  as  small  independent  states.  However,  the  Rocky  Mountains 
and  associated  mountain  systems  will  warn  the  political  geographer  to 
seek  in  these  physiographic  conditions  more  than  a  single  favorable 
condition.  In  the  mountainous  American  West  not  even  the  political 
subdivisions  have  tended  to  be  small.20  Of  the  ten  independent  republics 
of  South  America,  three  are  small  countries;  however,  only  one  of  the 

20  Semple,  op.  cit.,  p.  95,  speaks  of  "28  different  Indian  stocks  .  .  .  between  the 
Pacific  coast  and  the  eastern  slope  of  the  Sierra  Nevada  and  Cascade  Range,"  but  she 
speaks  neither  of  states,  nor  can  her  historical  statement  be  used  as  an  argument  in 
Dolitical  geography. 


SIZE  57 

three,  Ecuador,  is  a  mountain  country;  neither  Uruguay  nor  Paraguay 
are  in  the  Andes. 

It  has  been  said  that  the  existence  of  small  or  large  political  units  is 
a  function  of  physical  geographic  factors.  This  statement  can  be  main- 
tained only  in  a  very  generalized  and  qualified  form.  Latin  America 
seems  to  present  a  good  case  for  such  a  contention.  Many  small  political 
units  exist  in  the  islands  and  the  mountainous  isthmus  of  Central  America; 
several  medium-sized  states  are  in  the  Andine  West;  the  only  two  large 
states  are  in  the  eastern  plains  of  South  America.  Even  the  mountainous 
Central  American  islands  are  not  entirely  politically  united.  The  partition 
of  Hispaniola  between  Haiti  and  San  Domingo  may  find  some  justifi- 
cation in  both  human  and  physical  geography.  However,  this  is  largely 
a  result  of  historical  accident.  History  rather  than  physical  geographic 
conditions  will  explain  the  irrational  mosaic  of  the  political  map  of  the 
Lesser  Antilles,  or  the  division  of  tiny  St.  Martin  between  the  Dutch 
and  French.  It  may  be  said  that  the  nature  of  small  islands,  like  that 
of  secluded  mountain  cantons,  makes  it  easier  to  administer  them  as  units 
than  as  parts  of  larger  units.  But  no  conclusion  is  warranted  as  to  whether 
this  unit  should  be  an  independent  state,  an  autonomous  region,  or  an 
administrative  unit  on  the  same  level  as  other  similar  units. 

Even  such  a  limited  dependency  of  the  size  of  political  units  on 
physical  geographic  conditions  can  be  established  only  for  certain  periods. 
The  Greek  islands  were  independent  kingdoms  in  the  time  of  Homer, 
they  are  not  even  administrative  units  today.  It  is  undeniable  that  tech- 
nological progress  has  made  possible  the  consolidation  of  larger  states, 
and  within  states,  of  larger  divisions,  leading  to  more  efficient  political 
and  economic  administration.  Nevertheless,  to  establish  a  connection  be- 
tween technological  progress  and  a  trend  promoting  units  of  increasing 
size  is  possible  only  with  numerous  qualifications,  as  has  been  shown 
above.  Despite  technological  progress  there  are  also  strong  tendencies 
in  the  opposite  direction.  The  size  of  political  units  and  structures  is 
shaped  by  the  action  and  counteraction  of  all  these  diverse  forces. 


CHAPTER 


3 


Shape 


CONTIGUOUS  AND  NONCONTIGUOUS  STATE  AREAS 

While  few  people  will  question  the  political  significance  of  the  size 
of  a  state,  many  more  will  be  in  doubt  as  to  whether  its  shape  deserves 
special  attention.  The  shape  of  a  state  is  in  many  respects  a  haphazard 
characteristic  without  much  significance.  However,  in  other  respects, 
shape  has  a  definite  meaning.  An  obvious  example  is  the  distinction 
between  states  which  have  a  contiguous  area  and  those  which  have  not. 
The  average  educated  person  might  be  inclined  on  first  sight  to  regard 
a  state  possessing  a  contiguous  area  as  the  normal  form,  and  noncontig- 
uous state  territories  as  inherently  weak.  He  will  probably  remember 
states  consisting  of  noncontiguous  areas  (Fig.  3-1)  because  they  are 
anomalous.  Pakistan,  with  its  outlier  in  East  Pakistan,  and  Germany  be- 
tween 1919  and  1939,  with  its  outlier  in  East  Prussia,  will  come  to  mind. 
The  latter  has  not  survived,  and  was  during  its  existence  a  continuous 
source  of  irritation  and  complaints.  The  soundness  of  the  Pakistan  solution 
has  still  to  stand  the  test  of  history. 

These  two  examples  are  widely  known.  Perhaps  it  is  also  still  remem- 
bered that  an  attempt  was  once  made  to  create  the  new  state  of  Israel 
with  several  non-contiguous  areas  and  that  this  attempt  miscarried  from 
its  beginnings.  Forgotten,  except  by  a  few  specialists,  are  other  conflicts 
such  as  those  connected  with  the  Portuguese  area— often  called  an  enclave 
—of  Cabinda,  north  of  the  Congo  mouth.  As  a  result  of  the  creation  of 
the  Congo  state,  Cabinda  was  separated  from  the  main  Portuguese  colony 
of  Angola. 

58 


A. 


DISPUTED  KASHMIR 

AND  THE 

CEASE  FIRE  LINE 


ti 


N 


-1 

i 


v 


4 


TIBET 


4a3b 

WEST   ;MW 


i 


Lhasa 


/■— V 


\ 


Delhi 


v-^\ r*- — - *    /     / 


BURMA 


Fig.  3-1.  Pakistan:  A  Non-contiguous  State  Area. 


59 


60  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

The  German  and  Pakistan  examples  of  noncontiguous  territories  have 
in  common  the  fact  that  communication  between  their  disconnected  parts 
is  possible  by  sea,  that  this  connection  is  devious  and  slow,  and  that  land 
connections  via  the  territory  of  other  states,  although  more  convenient, 
were  impeded  by  the  irritating  restrictions  usual  to  political  frontiers. 
The  memory  of  the  hostile  clashes  which  gave  impetus  to  these  recent 
creations  adds  to  the  irritating  features  of  such  noncontiguous  areas. 

ENCLAVES  AND  EXCLAVES 

It  is  striking  that  little  irritation  appears  to  be  present  in  certain  small 
areas  that  are  completely  surrounded  by  the  territory  of  another  state. 
This  lack  of  conflict  is  due  mainly  to  the  smallness  of  these  areas  and 
their  lack  of  importance,  but  also  to  the  fact  that  they  have  been  in 
existence  for  many  years  and  have  developed  satisfactory  ways  of  co-exist- 
ence. The  best  known  examples  are  the  state  of  the  Vatican  City  and  the 
Republic  of  San  Marino,  both  within  Italian  territory.  The  creation— or 
perhaps  better  re-creation— of  the  Papal  State  ended  a  period  of  friction 
going  back  to  1870  and  in  some  respects  to  the  Napoleonic  seizure  of 
Rome.  The  Swiss  canton  Appenzell  (161  square  miles),  which  is  com- 
pletely surrounded  by  the  territory  of  the  larger  canton  St.  Gallen  (777 
square  miles),  might  be  considered  a  purely  internal  administrative 
arrangement,  if  it  had  not  existed  before  Switzerland  became  a  relatively 
close-knit  federation. 

Another  case  in  point  is  that  of  the  Rritish  protectorate  Basutoland 
which,  with  a  native  population  of  over  half  a  million,  is  completely 
surrounded  by  the  Union  of  South  Africa.  Originally  an  organization  of 
small  Bantu  tribes  united  in  defense  against  the  advancing  Zulu,  Mata- 
bele,  and  other  Kaffir  tribes,  Basutoland  played  its  role  on  the  frontier 
between  Boers,  British,  and  Bantus  ( Fig.  3-2 ) .  The  creation  of  the  Union 
of  South  Africa  left  it  an  enclave  in  the  midst  of  Union  territory.  Over- 
grazing, soil  erosion,  mountainous  terrain,  as  well  as  government  by 
reactionary  tribal  chiefs  and  the  desire  of  the  Union  to  annex  it  make 
the  future  of  this  unusual  configuration  rather  doubtful.  Similar  is  the 
position  of  Swaziland  (with  a  population  of  close  to  200,000),  also  a 
British  protectorate.  Although  it  borders  with  Portuguese  Mozambique 
for  a  short  distance,  it  is  for  all  practical  purposes  an  enclave  and  at  the 
mercy  of  the  Union  of  South  Africa.  The  "Apartheid"  segregation  policy 
of  the  Union  of  South  Africa  government  is  increasingly  changing  the 
political  map  of  this  country  into  a  checkerboard  of  white-man  territory 


SHAPE 


61 


^ 


Pretoria         (V- 


Johannesburg 


0     50    100        200  Km 


IE 


3 


Lit. 


Fig.  3-2.  Basutoland:  An  Enclave  in  the  Union  of  South  Africa. 


and  reserves  and  compounds  of  the  native  population.  By  strict  regulations 
which  require  travel  documents  for  African  males  who  wish  to  move 
from  district  to  district,  or  who  want  to  leave  their  reserves,  or  want  to 
enter  a  proclaimed  labor  area,  the  separation  of  white  and  native  within 
the  Union  has  been  accomplished  to  a  point  where,  internally,  the  native 
territory  is  composed  of  noncontiguous  enclaves  which  are  firmly  and 
centrally  supervised  by  the  central  government. 

Other  enclaves,  because  of  their  small  area  and  the  lack  of  international 
friction  involved,  are  likely  to  escape  notice.  Within  Swiss  territory, 
Germany  owns  the  tiny  enclave  of  Biisingen  east  of  Schaffhausen,  and 
Italy  the  enclave  of  Campione  on  Lago  di  Lugano.  Spain  retains  the 
enclave  of  Llivia  in  the  Pyrenees.  Even  the  tiny  Portuguese  possession  of 


62  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

Damao,  its  main  part  itself  not  a  true  exclave  because  it  lies  on  the  coast, 
includes  two  outlying  territories,  Dadara  and  Nagar  Aveli,  which  are  true 
enclaves  in  Indian  territory  and  are  separated  from  Damao  by  approxi- 
mately six  miles  of  Indian  territory.  A  modern  development  is  the  Swiss 
airport  of  Basel  which  is  an  enclave  near  the  French  city  of  Mulhouse. 
Because  no  suitable  area  could  be  found  on  Swiss  soil  a  treaty  was  con- 
cluded which  left  the  sovereignty  with  France,  but  ceded  the  area  for  the 
airport  to  Switzerland  in  every  other  respect.  Still  less  known  because  not 
recognizable  as  exclaves  of  one  country  or  enclaves  of  another  are  the 
areas  of  Jungbluth  and  of  the  Kleine  Walser  Tal.  They  belong  to  Austria 
and  seem  on  the  map  connected  with  it;  however,  due  to  high  mountains 
they  are  accessible  from  Austria  only  via  Germany  territory.  After  the 
"Anschluss"  in  1938  Germany  annexed  these  two  areas  to  Bavaria,  which 
move  was  only  an  administrational  reorganization  under  the  circum- 
stances. The  emergence  of  Austria  as  an  independent  country  in  1945 
restored  the  previous  conditions. 

More  frequent  than  on  the  international  scene  is  the  fragmented  shape 
of  provinces  in  federal  states  or  other  political  subdivisions.  In  its  frag- 
mentation into  some  twenty  parts,  the  German  state  of  Braunschweig 
was  an  extreme  case.  It  lasted  into  the  Hitler  period.  India  before  1948 
is  another  area  where  numerous  examples  could  be  found.  Here  British 
rule  had  frozen  the  conditions  of  the  eighteenth  century,  which  had 
resulted  from  the  collapse  of  the  central  authority  of  the  Moghuls.  This 
anarchical  situation,  characterized  by  the  breakup  of  India  into  a  crazy 
quilt  of  mostly  small  political  units,  would  not  have  lasted  long  if  India 
could  have  solved  her  problems  without  foreign  interference.  Baroda  was 
split  into  five  major  and  some  thirty  minor  parts,  some  of  them  still  sur- 
viving as  exclaves  of  Bombay  in  the  Saurashtra  Union.  Cases  of  frag- 
mentation can  be  found  elsewhere,  even  in  countries  that  are  generally 
and  rightly  regarded  as  uniform.  In  Spain  the  area  of  Ademuz  is  an 
outlier  (in  the  province  of  Teruel)  of  the  province  of  Valencia.  In  Eng- 
land, Dudley,  a  town  of  Worcestershire,  is  an  outlier  within  Staffordshire. 

Exclaves  of  one  political  unit  are  not  necessarily  enclaves  in  another— 
they  do  not  always  result  in  a  perforated  outline  within  the  map  of 
another  political  unit.  It  is  not  so  in  the  case  of  East  Prussia  or  of  East 
Pakistan.  On  the  other  hand,  the  existence  of  enclaves  does  not  necessarily 
imply  that  they  are  exclaves  of  another  state.  The  City  of  the  Vatican  and 
San  Marino  are  completely  surrounded  by  Italian  territory;  they  are  true 
enclaves  without  being  exclaves. 

Two  outstanding  examples  of  enclaves  in  recent  history  are  the  cities 


SHAPE  63 

of  Berlin  and  Vienna,  the  latter  until  recently  occupied  by  troops  of  the 
Western  powers,  and  in  part  by  Russian  troops  which  also  occupied  the 
surrounding  country  while  in  Berlin  the  satellite  East  German  state  rules 
one  half  of  the  city  and  the  surrounding  country.  Public  services  are 
common  to  both  parts  of  these  cities,  and  in  Vienna  the  boundary  was 
invisible  most  of  the  time  for  the  natives.  Throughout  this  period,  Vienna 
remained  still  the  capital  of  Austria  and  the  Austrian  government  and 
parliament  had  their  seat  there.  Vienna  exerted  also  in  other  respects  its 
central  function.  It  was  an  exclave  only  for  the  Western  occupying  forces. 
As  such  it  had  the  further  anomaly  that  two  airfields  constituted  tiny 
exclaves  some  distance  from  the  city,  administered  by  the  British  and 
Americans  respectively. 

West  Berlin  comes  closer  to  the  concept  of  a  genuine  exclave,1  both 
for  the  occupation  forces  and  for  the  (West)  German  Federal  Republic. 
As  its  contacts  with  the  surrounding  territory  have  been  more  and  more 
restricted,  the  boundary  of  West  Berlin  has  become  a  true  international 
boundary  (Fig.  3-3). 

Within  provinces,  counties,  and  so  forth,  perforation  frequently  results 
from  the  autonomous  administration  granted  to  urban  centers  in  the  midst 
of  rural  areas.  This  last  feature  is  seldom  noticed  by  the  observer  not 
directly  concerned  with  local  municipal  problems  and  is  hardly  regarded 
as  an  anomaly.  It  may  date  as  far  back  as  those  other  truly  anomalous 
configurations  on  the  international  map,  but  now  such  features  emerge 
continuously  as  natural  by-products  of  modern  economic  and  political 
developments.  Under  the  law  of  the  Commonwealth  of  Virginia,  settle- 
ments become  incorporated  cities  with  administration  distinct  from  that 
of  the  county  as  soon  as  they  attain  a  certain  size.  Similarly  exclaves  and 
enclaves  have  developed  quite  recently  in  rapidly  growing  metropolitan 
areas  by  incorporation  of  noncontiguous  pieces  of  land  for  public  utilities, 
or  by  the  resistance  of  old  established  communities  against  incorporation 
(Fig.  2-11,  p.  55). 

In  contrast  to  these  developments  are  some  exclaves  which  originated 
far  back,  in  history  in  some  cases  several  centuries.  They  are  relics  of 
what  have  become  obsolete  political  concepts :  princes  acquired  territories 
for  their  states  in  the  same  manner  in  which  they  would  have  acquired 
private  property.  As  a  result  a  political  unit,  like  an  estate  or  a  farm, 
might  consist  of  several  unconnected  parts.  Like  modern  farmers,  sover- 

1  G.  W.  S.  Robinson,  "West  Berlin:  The  Geography  of  an  Exclave,"  Geographical 
Review,  Vol.  43  (October,  1953),  pp.  541-557;  P.  Scholler,  "Stadtgeographische  Prob- 
leme  des  geteilten  Berlin,"  Erdkunde,  Vol.  7  (March,  1953),  pp.  1-11. 


64 


THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 


Fig.  3-3.  Berlin:  An  Exclave. 


eigns  of  such  states  might  try  to  accomplish  contiguity  as  a  convenience, 
but  not  as  a  matter  of  principle.  Under  feudal  conditions  traveling  from 
one  property  to  another  across  "foreign  territory"  did  not  involve  pass- 
ports or,  necessarily,  customs.  In  other  cases  noncontiguous  areas  have 
been  acquired  by  chance  heritage,  or  in  order  to  get  a  foothold  in  an 
area  which  was  desired  because  of  its  richness.  In  time,  a  deliberate 
policy  of  acquiring  connected  territories  was  pursued.  An  example  in  the 
United  States  is  the  Western  Reserve  in  present  northern  Ohio,  belonging 
once  to  Connecticut.  In  Europe,  history  records  many  such  incidents:  e.g. 
the  Hapsburgs,  counts  in  northern  Switzerland,  became  dukes  of  Austria 
far  to  the  East.  This  acquisition  was  a  by-product  of  the  elevation  of 
the  first  Rudolf  to  the  royal  throne  and  of  the  need  to  replace  the  domain 
lost  during  the  preceding  period  of  anarchy.  The  descendants  of  Rudolf  I 
worked  consciously  to  build  a  land  bridge  between  Austria  and  their 
Swiss  dominions.  Carinthia  and  the  Tyrol  were  acquired,  but  a  gap 
remained  and  the  Swiss  territories  were  finally  lost.  More  fortunate  were 
the  Hohenzollerns  of  Rrandenburg  who  acquired  outlying  territories  on 


SHAPE  65 

the  Rhine  and  in  East  Prussia  by  inheritance  in  the  seventeenth  century; 
they  succeeded  in  forming  a  contiguous  state  territory  extending  from 
the  Rhine  to  Memel  after  two  centuries  of  struggle. 

In  the  feudal  age  in  Europe  or  India,  or  wherever  a  comparable  stage 
existed,  political  allegiance  was  a  personal  matter  and  not  a  territorial 
one.  The  Germanic  tribes  and  heirs  of  their  legal  concepts  carried  this 
idea  to  an  extreme.  Every  person  carried  the  laws  of  his  origin  with  him. 
The  same  idea  was  modified  in  the  system  of  "capitulations,"  according 
to  which  Europeans  in  many  states  of  Asia  and  Africa,  even  if  born  there, 
could  be  tried  only  before  the  authorities  of  their  country  of  origin.  Only 
twenty  years  ago  a  map  of  Asia  would  show  large  areas  where  the 
sovereignty  of  the  countries  was  not  complete  because  of  the  extraterri- 
torial status  of  foreigners.  In  the  Byzantine  Empire  and  later  in  Turkey 
it  was  customary  for  communities  of  non-Islamic  faith  to  live  in  separate 
quarters  under  autonomous  administration  (millet).  Following  this  cus- 
tom, the  privilege  of  living  together  was  given  to  merchants  coming  from 
the  same  city,  from  Venice,  Pisa,  or  Genoa.  These  quarters  maintained 
their  own  separate  laws  and  were  often  surrounded  by  a  wall.  They 
became  a  kind  of  territorial  enclave.  Turkey  never  relinquished  sover- 
eignty over  such  areas  as  did  China  and  India  over  the  factories  of 
Portuguese,  Dutch,  and  other  Western  European  powers.  Here  finally 
the  transition  from  the  personal  to  territorial  status  was  completed  and 
enclaves  developed. 

The  establishment  of  such  extraterritorial  trading  posts  signifies  the 
beginnings  of  modern  European  colonial  imperialism.  These  colonies 
distinguish  modern  empires,  except  the  Russian  Empire,  from  ancient 
empires  in  that  they  are  characterized  by  a  fragmented  shape.  Fragmen- 
tation of  this  kind  comes  clearly  into  focus  when  colonies  shake  off  their 
colonial  bonds  and  become  independent  partners.  Then  the  manifold 
problems  of  dependent  outlying  possessions  are  superseded  by  the  prob- 
lem of  equal  rights  under  different  conditions.  This  has  led  to  the  breaking 
away  of  the  American  republics  from  England,  Spain,  and  Portugal,  and 
in  our  time  threatens  with  dissolution  the  British  Commonwealth  of 
Nations  in  many  parts  of  the  world. 

The  nineteenth  and  twentieth  century  concept  of  nationalism  has 
had  a  strong  influence  in  changing  the  shape  of  many  states  as  well  as 
in  determining  what  constitutes  a  desirable  or  undesirable  shape.  Two 
major  instances  of  fragmented  shape  are  mentioned  above,  East  Prussia 
and  East  Pakistan.  If  the  concept  of  nationalism  were  applied  consistently 
to  shaping  of  state  territories  it  could  become  of  immense  importance 


66  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

in  federal  states  such  as  those  of  the  Soviet  Union.  But  despite  the  Soviet's 
proclaimed  adherence  to  the  principle  of  national  autonomy,  economic 
advantages  of  contiguous  areas  weighed  heavier  in  shaping  the  feder- 
ated autonomous  and  constituent  republics.  Even  the  subordination  of 
Nakhitchevan  to  the  noncontiguous  Azerbaijan  Soviet  Republic  does  not 
really  contradict  this  fact,  as  Nakhitchevan  is  a  mountain  canton  having 
little  contact  with  neighboring  Soviet  Armenia.2 

ISLAND  STATES 

In  a  looser  sense,  noncontiguous  states  are  also  those  states  the  territory 
of  which  is  composed  partially  or  entirely  of  islands.  Where  such  islands 
are  coastal  islands,  or  clearly  belong  to  one  group,  as  do  the  four  main 
islands  of  Japan,  lack  of  contiguity  of  the  political  area  is  hardly  felt. 
Where  islands  are  no  more  than— usually— three  miles  distant  from  the 
mainland  or  each  other,  they  are  legally  contiguous,  because  they  are  still 
within  the  so-called  territorial  waters.  Norway,  with  its  numerous  coastal 
islands,  offers  a  good  illustration.3  Groups  of  islands  such  as  the  Tonga 
Islands,  the  Hawaiian  Islands,  the  Azores,  and  many  others  also  form 
obvious  units,  although  the  distance  between  individual  islands  may  be 
scores  of  miles.  It  does  not  matter  whether  such  groups  have  a  history 
of  political  unity— as  do  the  Hawaiian  Islands  and  the  still  functioning 
kingdom  of  the  Tonga  Islands— or  whether  they  have  attained  political 
unity  only  since  they  were  "discovered"— as  have  the  Cape  Verde  Islands 
and  the  Azores. 

Large  bodies  of  intervening  water  constitute  a  problem  which  is 
aggravated  if  other  sovereignties  are  actually  nearer  to  the  outlying  area 
than  the  country  to  which  it  officially  belongs. 

The  long-drawn  discussions  concerning  statehood  for  Hawaii  and 
Alaska  are  an  example.  Though  other  issues,  such  as  the  racial  composition 
and  political  party  inclinations  of  the  inhabitants  may  be  the  main  cause 
for  delay  in  extending  statehood,  these  factors  would  not  carry  weight 
in  a  contiguous  area.  On  the  other  hand,  the  Azores  are  regarded  by 
Portugal  as  an  integral  part  of  the  mainland.  France  even  regards  northern 
Algeria  as  part  of  metropolitan  France. 

2  A  few  small  autonomous  oblasts,  those  of  the  Adyge,  Cherkess,  and  Nagornot- 
Karabakh,  are  enclaves  in  other  administrative  units.  The  two  national  Okrugs,  the 
Aginskoye  Buryat-Mongol  and  the  Ust-Ordyn  Buryat-Mongol,  are  actually  exclaves 
of  the  Buryat-Mongol  autonomous  Soviet  Socialist  Bepublic. 

3  Norway,  like  all  the  Scandinavian  countries,  claims  a  belt  of  five  nautical  miles 
as  territorial  waters. 


SHAPE  67 

THE  FACTOR  OF  COMPACTNESS 

In  countries  which  include  island  territories  and  yet  constitute  a  fairly 
compact  unit— such  as  Great  Britain,  Japan,  the  Philippines,  and  to  some 
extent  Greece,  Denmark,  and  Norway— contact  between  islands  or  be- 
tween island  and  mainland  may  be  easier  than  between  adjacent  parts 
of  the  continental  territory.  Intercourse  was  never  difficult  across  the 
Aegean  Sea  between  the  Greek  Islands  and  Greece.  Even  continental 
parts  of  Greece  are  today  in  many  cases  more  easily  accessible  by  boat 
than  by  mountain  trails  or  winding  roads.  Similar  conditions  exist  in  the 
Japanese  Islands,  where  contacts  across  the  Inland  Sea  are  easy  and  were 
so  before  the  age  of  railroads.  Yeddo,  the  northernmost  island,  though 
separated  by  the  narrow  Strait  of  Hakodate,  was  joined  to  the  other 
islands  very  late  because,  among  other  reasons,  navigation  across  the 
strait  was  difficult  under  the  frequently  adverse  weather  conditions.  On 
the  other  hand,  intercourse  over  land  routes  becomes  a  difficult  problem 
in  countries  where  deserts  take  the  place  of  a  dividing  ocean.  Such  deserts 
are  the  Sahara  between  French  North  Africa  and  the  Sudan,  and  the  Inner 
Asian  deserts  between  Russia  proper  and  Turkestan.  In  these  areas  maps 
which  do  not  stress  physical  features  are  misleading.  Physical  factors  play 
a  part  in  much  smaller  countries  over  short  distances.  Until  a  few  years 
ago,  Vorarlberg,  the  westernmost  province  of  Austria,  could  not  be 
reached  directly  from  the  rest  of  the  country  when  snow  blocked  the  pass 
route  over  the  Arlberg.  Similarly,  the  canton  Tessin  was  separated  from 
the  rest  of  Switzerland  when  the  St.  Gotthard  pass  was  closed.  In  all 
these  cases  only  modern  communications  have  rendered  the  apparent 
compactness  a  reality.  Powerful  governments  had  also  in  other  cases 
to  develop  and  protect  communications  across  difficult  terrain  such  as 
mountains,  forests,  and  deserts.  However,  only  constant  vigilance  and 
investment  of  capital  can  keep  open  such  routes. 

CIRCUM-MARINE  STATES 

Under  such  conditions  it  would  hardly  be  justifiable  to  overlook  the 
role  of  sea  transportation  in  defining  the  idea  of  a  compact  state.  It  makes 
understandable  the  fact  that  circum-marine  states  can  have  a  fundamental 
compactness.  We  can  envisage  the  ancient  Roman  Empire  as  a  compact 
unit,  with  the  Mediterranean  Sea  as  an  integral  part,  if  we  take  into 
consideration  that  sea  lanes  in  general  were  more  efficient  in  antiquity 
than  land  routes,  until  the  Romans  built  their  military  road-net.  If  we 


Fig.  3-4.  British  Influence  around  the  Indian  Ocean  between  World  Wars  I  and  II: 
(1)  British  colonies;  (2)  Dutch  colonies;  (3)  Portuguese  colonies. 


68 


SHAPE  69 

insist  on  regarding  only  the  terra  firma  as  constituent  part  of  the  Roman 
Empire,  one  of  the  oddest  shaped  territories  would  emerge.  The  same 
is  true  for  other  circum-marine  empires,  such  as  the  former  Swedish 
empire  around  the  Baltic  Sea,  and  the  Turkish  empire  around  the 
Black  Sea  and  eastern  Mediterranean.  In  this  category  belong  even 
countries  of  shape  as  familiar  as  the  British  dominion  around  the  Irish 
Sea,  and  in  the  Middle  Ages  the  British  realm  on  both  sides  of  the  British 
Channel.  In  modern  times  such  circum-marine  empires  have  become  rare. 
The  British  domination,  between  the  two  World  Wars,  of  most  coastal 
territories  around  the  Indian  Ocean  is  the  most  recent  example,  especially 
if  one  regarded  the  Dutch  and  Portuguese  colonies,  though  nominally 
belonging  to  foreign  independent  states,  as  practically  at  the  disposal 
of  the  British  (Fig.  3-4).  Today  this  circum-Indic  empire  is  rapidly  dis- 
solving, and  the  dominions,  despite  their  official  ties  to  the  Common- 
wealth, are  apparently  less  closely  bound  to  the  policy  of  the  United 
Kingdom.  Their  territory  is  not  as  unquestionably  at  Britain's  disposal 
as  those  Portuguese  and  presumably  also  Dutch  foreign  colonies  once 
were.  The  only  true  circum-marine  state  of  today  is  Indonesia,  a  state 
around  the  Java  Sea  (Fig.  3-5).  Its  peculiar  character  is  underlined  by 
the  lack  of  railroads  and  highways  on  all  islands  except  Java.  Indonesia 
is  dependent  upon  sea  lanes.4 

SHAPE  AFFECTED  BY  A  STRATEGIC  BASES  CONTROL  SYSTEM 

These  circum-marine  empires  have  been  superseded  by  a  different  type 
of  control  based  on  the  possession  of  skillfully  selected  and  strategically 
distributed  bases.5  The  Mediterranean  became  a  British  sea  as  the  result 
of  a  combination  of  these  bases  with  political  controls.  Britain  acquired 
Gibraltar  in  1704,  the  Maltese  islands  in  1800,  and  Cyprus  in  1878.  These 
footholds  were  augmented  by  two  powerful  political  supports— political 
control  of  Egypt  from  1882  to  1936,  fortified  by  the  military  base  in  the 
Suez  Canal  zone,  and  "a  skilful  diplomacy  which  produced  allies  and 
neutrals  within  the  Mediterranean  basin."  6  These  factors  are  what  made 
the  Mediterranean  a  British  sea  in  the  nineteenth  century,  not  territorial 
possessions  along  the  Mediterranean  shore.  In  the  post-World  War  II 
world,  the  growing  threat  of  airpower  and  submarines  has   altogether 

4W.  G.  East  and  O.  H.  K.  Spate,  The  Changing  Map  of  Asia  (London,  1950), 
p.  217. 

5  See  also  pp.  70,  157. 

6  W.  G.  East,  "The  Mediterranean:  Pivot  of  Peace  and  War,"  Foreign  Affairs, 
Vol.32  (1953),  p.  623. 


« 
E 


3 
u 

U 

■— 

« 
O 

c 


c 
o 
U 


a 
£ 

X! 

w 

e 


s 
o 

c 


up 

o 

— 


70 


SHAPE  71 

changed  the  role  of  the  Mediterranean  area,  especially  of  the  Mediter- 
ranean-Red Sea  route,  in  world  affairs.  In  recognition  of  these  basic 
changes,  we  witness  today  the  evolution  of  a  new  circum-Atlantic  power 
combination  of  the  NATO  countries  in  which  the  United  States  and 
Britain  are  the  main  partners,  and  which  is  based  on  a  broad  European 
and  African  defense.  The  American  Mediterranean,  the  Caribbean  Sea,  is 
dominated  by  the  United  States  from  Puerto  Rico,  the  Virgin  Islands, 
Guantanamo  on  Cuba,  Panama,  and  the  leased  bases  on  Trinidad,  in 
British  Guiana,  on  Jamaica,  the  Bahamas,  Antigua,  and  St.  Lucia  (Fig. 
3-6).  An  American  Pacific  dominion  is  taking  shape,  with  Okinawa  and 
the  bases  on  the  Philippines  as  westernmost  outposts.  The  Soviet  Union 
has  tried  to  create  a  Baltic  dominion,  more  in  the  form  of  the  older 
empires,  occupying  all  coasts  from  Leningrad  to  Riigen,  but  also  using 
the  bases  concept  by  the  acquisition  of  Porkkala-Udd  on  the  Finnish 
coast,  which,  however,  was  returned  to  Finland  in  1956. 

THE  VALUE  OF  SHAPE 

Political  and  military  geographers  have  tried  to  blame  certain  unhappy 
events  in  the  history  of  some  countries  on  the  shape  of  their  territories. 
In  recent  decades  it  was  fashionable  to  compare  such  states  as  France 
and  Czechoslovakia  and  explain  the  relative  stability  of  the  French  state 
by  its  compact,  almost  pentagonal  shape,  and  blame  the  endangered 
position  of  Czechoslovakia  on  its  elongated  form. 

Even  if  it  were  possible  to  separate  the  factors  which  make  for  the 
stability  or  instability  of  France  and  Czechoslovakia,  and  to  isolate  the 
influence  of  shape  in  itself,  this  influence  would  still  need  explanation. 
There  was  a  time  when  French  kings  felt  that  their  country  was  sur- 
rounded by  Spanish-Hapsburg  possessions  and  that  in  order  to  break  the 
threatening  encirclement  it  would  be  advisable  to  acquire  territory  in 
Italy,  which  would  indeed  create  a  tongue-like  extrusion  from  the  com- 
pact area  of  France,  but  would  make  encirclement  more  difficult.  Simi- 
larly, the  Czechs  felt  that  a  compact  Bohemian  state  (plus  Moravia) 
would  be  in  constant  danger  because  of  being  surrounded  by  the  ter- 
ritories of  two  German-speaking  countries,  Germany  and  Austria,  whereas 
the  odd-looking  eastern  extension  through  Slovakia  and  Podkarpatska 
Rus  would  provide  territorial  contact  between  the  main  part  of  their 
country  and  a  friendly  power  ( Rumania ) ,  bring  their  territory  into  close 
proximity  to  another  potential  ally  against  Germany  (U.S.S.R.),  and  give 
them  a  long  boundary  with  another  Slavic  state  ( Poland ) . 


0) 

a 


H3 
V 

c 

°E 

£ 

c 
< 

en 

c 

rt 
ai 
.a 
-O 

"C 
eS 

u 

01 

H 

CO 

6 

t-H 


72 


SHAPE  73 

It  seems  fair  to  state  that  shape  in  itself  has  little  meaning,  but  that  it 
has  to  be  taken  into  consideration  as  one  factor  which,  together  with 
other  factors,  constitutes  the  political  geography  of  a  country. 

The  problem  of  shape  is  especially  devoid  of  meaning  if  it  is  regarded 
as  a  problem  of  geometrical  shape.  The  claim  that  a  compact  and,  ideally, 
a  circular  shape  is  the  best  for  the  safety  of  a  country  is  a  theoretical 
deduction  without  confirmation  in  experience.  The  only  meaningful  ques- 
tion is,  whether  and  in  how  far  the  political  shape  parallels  certain  natural 
features  and  factors  of  human  geography.  Chile  and  Norway  have  an 
extremely  elongated  shape,  more  so  than  Czechoslovakia,  but  both  have 
displayed  a  persistency  and  stability  of  shape  less  subject  to  changes 
throughout  the  centuries  than  the  compact  outline  of  France.  Before 
World  War  II  the  idea  of  boundaries  along  natural  features  was  much 
used  and  misused;  recently  it  has  been  too  much  discounted.  Norway, 
Chile,  an  island  state  such  as  Iceland,  or  a  mountain  state  surrounded 
by  deserts  such  as  Ethiopia  or  Yemen,  are  largely  congruent  with  a  natural 
geographical  region— Norway  and  Chile  to  a  slightly  lesser  degree.  Where 
Norway  reaches  in  the  southeast  across  the  mountains,  it  includes  all 
Norwegian-speaking  areas.  Czechoslovakia  did  not  attain  this  unity,  its 
physiographic  features  almost  nowhere  being  congruent  with  the  areas 
of  languages  and  nations  in  this  area.  For  this  reason,  and  only  for  this 
reason,  its  elongated  shape  is  so  vulnerable.  The  same  problem  of  vulner- 
ability has  arisen  in  Spain,  and  for  the  same  reason,  although  it  is  an 
outstanding  example  of  adaptation  to  physiographic  features.  Spain  had 
to  wrestle  with  repeated  attempts  at  dismemberment  in  its  Catalonian 
and  Basque  provinces.  Its  human  geography  does  not  fit  its  theoretically 
perfect  shape. 

"FORWARD  POINTS  OF  GROWTH" 

A  shape  often  regarded  as  a  handicap  to  the  economic  development 
and  military  safety  of  countries  is  that  involving  an  area  connected  with 
the  bulk  of  a  country  only  by  a  narrow  neck  of  land.  Such  shapes  have 
been  compared  with  peninsulas  and  promontories.  An  outstanding  ex- 
ample of  such  a  shape,  and  of  its  almost  perennially  endangered  position 
is  that  part  of  Sinkiang  known  as  Chinese  Turkestan.  For  long  periods 
this  area  was  connected  with  the  main  bulk  of  the  Chinese  Empire  only 
by  the  narrow  corridor  of  semidesert  Kansu  between  the  desert  of  Gobi 
and  the  mountains  of  Tibet.  Some  geographers  have  spoken  in  this 
connection   of  a   prompted   shape.7   At   one   time,   long   ago,   this   area 

7  C.  L.  White  and  G.  T.  Renner,  Human  Geography  (New  York,  1948),  p.  588. 


74  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

was  acquired  by  China  as  a  base  for  further  westward  penetration. 
German  geographers,  and  not  only  those  of  the  geopolitical  school,  spoke 
therefore  in  this  connection  of  Wachstumspitzen— "forward  points  of 
growth."  They  compared  such  forms  with  the  shoots  of  plants,  or  even 
with  the  advance  force  of  an  army.  Thus,  instead  of  indicating  weakness, 
it  appears  that  such  "proruptions"  may  under  certain  conditions  signify 
an  aggressive  vitality.  If  one  looks  at  the  former  Chinese  forward  points 
of  growth  through  Chinese  glasses,  from  China's  core  area,  one  under- 
stands how,  under  changed  political  conditions,  such  areas  can  become 
political  liabilities  and  economic  liabilities  as  well.  This  is  especially  true 
in  the  absence  of  rail  and  road  communications,  without  which  overland 
outposts  can  scarcely  be  an  integral  part  of  a  core  area.  Sinkiang  (which 
has  twice  the  area  of  France  but  a  population  of  only  about  four  million ) 
illustrates  the  withering-away  of  the  "forward  point  of  growth"  when  an 
expanding  neighboring  power  (the  U.S.S.R. )  drives  its  railroad  and  high- 
way net  closer  to  the  disputed  area,  in  an  effort  to  expand. 

The  case  of  Kashmir  has  been  interpreted  as  an  illustration  of  a  "forward 
point  of  growth  or  aggression"  being  established  against  the  resistance 
of  a  competing  power,  in  this  case  Pakistan.  It  may  well  be  that  this  is 
rather  an  attempt  to  hold  on  to  a  "point"  which  has  high  emotional  value 
and  might  serve  as  a  sensitive  observation  post  in  an  area  where  Pakistan, 
the  U.S.S.R.,  Chinese  Sinkiang,  and  Afghanistan  meet.  As  a  Wachstum- 
spitze,  the  value  is  probably  very  small,  because  communication  from 
Pathankot,  the  nearest  important  station  of  India,  to  the  valley  of  Kashmir 
leads  across  extremely  high,  roadless  passes  that  are  closed  by  snow  many 
months  of  the  year. 

The  tiny  princely  state  of  Sikkim  (2,745  square  miles;  population  in 
1951,  137,000;  cf.  Fig.  3-1)  offers  another  example  of  how  such  a  "forward 
point  of  growth"  degenerates  into  a  proruption  which  is  hard  to  defend. 
Pointing  like  an  arrowhead  toward  Tibet  (470,000  square  miles;  popula- 
tion about  three  million),  the  Himalayan  mountain  state  dominates  the 
main  trade  route  between  India  and  Tibet  and  thus  is  the  gateway  to 
Tibet.  From  here  the  British  made  their  successful  attempts  to  win  entry 
into  Tibet.  Today  its  demographic  composition,  linguistically  and  reli- 
giously closely  related  to  Chinese-held  Tibet,  makes  it  a  weak  point  in  the 
Indian  perimeter.  On  the  other  hand,  the  example  of  the  prosperous  and 
democratic  Indian  protectorate  may  make  itself  felt  in  poverty-stricken 
Tibet.  The  successful  agrarian  and  tax  reform  in  Sikkim,  which  super- 
seded absolute  rule  and  oppression  by  autocratic  landholders,  provides 


SHAPE 


75 


"W*. 


Fig.  3-7.  Portuguese  and  German  Expansion  in  Central  Africa. 


arguments  against  Communism  in  the  ideological  struggle  over  the  future 
of  Tibet. 

In  some  instances,  proruptions  have  been  intentionally  created  for 
purposes  of  aggression.  Several  examples  of  this  are  the  so-called  Caprivi 
strip,  which  extends  as  a  narrow  strip  from  the  northeastern  corner  of 
Southwest  Africa— a  German  colony,  when  it  was  devised— to  the  Zambesi 
river;  Portuguese  Mozambique  expanded  inland  along  the  Zambesi  at 
about  the  same  period  in  order  to  meet  Portuguese  colonization  advanc- 
ing from  the  Angola  West  African  coast  (Fig.  3-7);  the  narrow  coastal 
landscape  of  Tenasserim,  a  southern  extension  of  the  then  British  Burma 
toward  the  northward-growing  Malay  States  and  Straits  Settlements  offers 
another  illustration;  the  Alaskan  panhandle,  recording  the  Russian  ad- 
vance toward  California,  is  an  example  from  America. 

In  each  of  these  cases  the  Wachstumspitze,  the  forward  point  of  growth 
or  of  aggression,  lost  its  essential  character  at  the  time  when  the  core 
area  and  its  people  underwent  basic  changes,  or  when  their  outlook 
toward  the  forward  point  was  reversed.  The  Alaskan  panhandle  is  an 
illustration;  its  quality  as  a  Wachstumspitze  vanished  when  Russia  lost 
interest  in  American  expansion. 

All  these  examples  should  make  it  abundantly  clear  that  the  same  shape 
may  indicate  an  area  of  weakness  or  a  forward  point  of  growth  or  even 


76  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

of  aggression.  The  answer  cannot  be  found  by  focusing  attention  only  on 
the  shape  of  a  political  region.  Configurations  which  on  the  political  map 
resemble  a  Wachstumspitze  may  be  not  only  a  relic,  but  may  actually  be 
the  result  of  a  flanking  or  encirclement  movement  of  a  neighboring 
expansionist  nation  or  group  of  nations.  This  is  best  illustrated  by  the 
unhappy  spatial  relationship  in  which  Czechoslovakia  found  itself  prior 
to  1939  in  regard  to  Germany  and  Austria,  but  especially  after  the  Ger- 
mans had  occupied  Austria,  thus  closing  the  pincers  on  Czechoslovakia. 
To  the  uninformed,  or  politically  misinformed  German  onlooker,  the 
outflanked  or  almost  encircled  small  country  could  be  presented  as  a 
dagger  pointing  threateningly  toward  the  encircling  Nazi  Germany.  The 
map  published  in  General  Haushofer's  Journal  of  Geopolitics  in  1934  with 
the  caption  "Ein  Kleinstaat  Bedroht  Deutschland"  (A  Small  State 
Threatens  Germany)  offers  a  good  illustration  of  a  complete  distortion  of 
facts  by  abusing  the  map  as  a  weapon.  The  umbrella  of  airplanes  fanning 
out  from  the  alleged  Wachstwnspitze  of  Czechoslovakia  brought  home 
to  the  Germans,  fed  by  the  geopolitical  propaganda  of  the  Third  Reich, 
what  seemed  to  be  an  imminent  danger  of  German  cities  being  bombed 
by  the  air  force  of  Czechoslovakia.  Haushofer  did  not  stop  to  think  of 
how  the  same  map,  with  a  reversed  air-umbrella,  would  impress  the 
citizens  of  the  small  nation  which  was  watching  helplessly  while  the 
ominously  progressing  flanking  expansion  of  the  Third  Reich  reached  out 
for  more  and  more  Lebensraum  (living  space)   (Fig.  3-8). 

Clearly  the  mere  shapes  of  Czechoslovakia  and  Germany  on  the  political 
map  of  Central  Europe  do  not  supply  the  answer  to  the  question  of 
whether  and  where  in  their  spatial  relationships  forward  points  of  aggres- 
sion can  be  detected.  The  answer  can  be  found  only  if  one  weighs  the 
manifold  historical,  cultural,  ethnic,  and  economic  factors  which  have 
contributed  to  the  spatial  relationship  of  neighboring  nations  and  have 
become  crystallized,  even  temporarily,  in  what  the  map  reveals  as  odd- 
shape  relations.  It  should  be  added  that  the  study  of  mere  physical 
expansion  deals  with  but  part  of  the  problem.  The  policy  of  flanking 
or  encirclement  can  be  carried  out  by  means  of  physical  expansion  or 
by  the  conclusion  of  treaties  or  alliances.8  The  case  of  Czechoslovakia  is 
not  an  unusual  one.  Historical  geography  supplies  many  similar  illus- 
trations of  basic  changes  of  the  political  map  as  the  result  of  flanking 
movements  of  expanding  powers.  The  Mongolian  advance  on  India,  the 
Roman  drive  toward  western  Germany  show  the  aggressor  nations  in 

8  N.  J.  Spykman  and  A.  A.   Rollins,   "Geographic  Objectives   in   Foreign   Policy," 
American  Political  Science  Review  ( 1939 ) ,  p.  394. 


SHAPE 


77 


Fig.  3-8.  The  Map  as  a  Weapon  of  Geopolitics:  Czechoslovakia,  a  "Threat"  to  Nazi 

Germany. 

their  flanking  operations  against  the  attacked  nations,  just  as  classical 
encirclement  moves  can  be  seen  in  the  drives  of  Carthage,  and  later  Rome, 
against  the  Iberian  peninsula,  and  of  the  Romans  against  the  Germans.9 
If  a  forward  point  serves  the  purpose  of  establishing  contact  with 
another  area  it  is  called  a  corridor.  Such  corridors  have  been  established 
by  Colombia  and  Bolivia  in  order  to  win  access  to  the  Amazon  and  the 
Parana  rivers.  Neither  of  these  corridors  so  far  has  attracted  much  traffic. 
Far  more  important,  both  politically  and  economically,  was  the  Polish 
corridor,  designed  to  serve  as  a  real  corridor  between  landlocked  Poland 
and  the  sea  in  the  period  between  the  two  World  Wars.  A  large  part  of 
Poland's  overseas  traffic  passed  through  this  corridor  to  Danzig  and 
Gdynia,  as  well  as  some  traffic  which  would  have  gone  more  directly 
over  land  routes  but  thereby  would  have  had  to  cross  foreign  territory. 
A  similar  function  was  served  by  the  Finnish  corridor  of  Petsamo,  which 
opened  a  route  to  the  fishing  grounds  of  the  Arctic  Sea.  In  the  event  of 


9  O.  Maull,  Politische  Geographic  ( Berlin,  1925 ) ,  p.  96. 


78  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

the  closing  of  the  Baltic  by  ice  or  by  war,  Petsamo  provided  Finland 
with  an  opening  to  the  west  via  the  open  ocean. 

It  is  obvious  from  the  foregoing  that  the  political  geographer  will  find 
a  study  of  odd-shaped  nations— those  having  noncontiguous  areas  or 
extenuated  shapes— in  some  cases  fairly  rewarding.  Other  shapes  have 
little  significance  and  any  effort  to  fit  them  into  a  system  would  be 
artificial. 


CHAPTER 


4 


The  Nature  and  Functions 
or  Boundaries 


BOUNDARY  LINES  AND  BOUNDARY  ZONES 

We  have  discussed  political  units  under  the  tacit  assumption  that  they 
were  bordered  by  sharp,  definite  boundaries.  This  is  a  condition  which 
applies  at  present,  at  least  in  theory,  to  most  political  boundaries.  Yet  it 
is  in  sharp  contradistinction  to  conditions  which  existed  in  most  of  Europe 
in  the  past  and  in  some  non-European  continents  into  the  twentieth 
century.  Frontier  zones,  belts  of  no  man's  land,  and  even  overlapping 
sovereignties  were  then  the  rule.  A  rather  extensive  literature  1  deals  with 
the  development  of  boundary  lines  out  of  such  zones  or  related  vague 
features.  Somewhat  less  attention  has  been  paid  to  the  development  of 
boundary  lines  from  old  property,  especially  field  boundaries.  The  Romans 

1  No  complete  list  of  publications  on  this  subject  shall  be  given.  Among  the  more 
important  are  S.  B.  Jones,  Boundary-Making  (Washington,  1945);  P.  de  Lapradelle, 
La  Frontiere  (Paris,  1927);  O.  Lattimore,  Inner  Asian  Frontiers  of  China  (New  York, 
1939);  S.  W.  Boggs,  International  Boundaries  (New  York,  1940);  K.  Haushofer, 
Grenzen  (Berlin,  1927);  O.  Maull,  Politische  Geographie  (Berlin,  1925);  J.  Ancel,  La 
geographie  des  frontieres  (Paris,  1927);  B.  Hartshorne,  "Geography  and  Political 
Boundaries  in  Upper  Silesia,"  Annals  of  the  Association  of  American  Geography, 
Vol.  23  (1933),  pp.  195  ff.;  E.  Fischer,  "On  Boundaries,"  World  Politics,  Vol.  1,  No.  2 
(January,  1949),  pp.  196-222;  G.  N.  Curzon  of  Kedleston,  Frontiers,  2nd  ed.  (Oxford, 
1908);  J.  Soldi,  Die  Auffassung  der  natiirlichen  Grenzen  in  der  wissenschaftlichen 
Geographie  (Innsbruck,  1924);  Thomas  Holdich,  Political  Frontiers  and  Boundary 
Making  (London,  1916);  C.  B.  Fawcett,  Frontiers  (Oxford,  1918);  A.  E.  Moodie, 
Geography  Behind  Politics,  Ch.  5,  "Frontiers  and  Boundaries"  (London,  1947); 
A.  Melamid,  "The  Economic  Geography  of  Neutral  Territories,"  Geographical  Beview, 
Vol.  45  (July,  1955). 

79 


80  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

in  the  time  of  the  republic  used  the  plow  to  draw  the  boundary  (limes) 
of  a  newly  founded  colony  or  city.  With  the  development  of  the  Roman 
city-state  into  a  territorial  state  the  concept  of  strict  delimitation  spread 
and  became  basic  in  Roman  law.  Though  these  problems  will  be  men- 
tioned, wherever  pertinent,  the  main  interest  in  this  chapter  is  not  the 
historical  development  of  the  boundary  line,  but  rather  the  description 
of  the  presently  existing  boundary  lines,  their  functions  and  problems. 
A  later  chapter  will  deal  with  boundary  zones  in  the  political  conflicts 
of  nations  today.  Although  we  maintain  that  there  is  a  basic  difference 
between  boundary  lines  and  boundary  zones,  we  shall  not  insist  on  re- 
garding as  boundary  lines  only  the  mathematical  line  of  one  dimension. 
For  all  practical  purposes  a  wooden  barrier,  having  a  width  of  a  few 
inches,  a  grassy  path  between  fields,  having  a  width  of  a  few  feet,  or 
even  a  lane  cut  into  a  forest,  having  a  width  of  a  few  yards,  are  boundary 
lines.  Roundary  zones  exist  only  where  the  space  between  two  countries 
is  wide  enough  to  permit  man  to  live  within  it,  either  actually  or  poten- 
tially. In  lands  that  are  inhabited  by  sedentary  populations,  this  distinction 
is  satisfactory.  In  the  rapidly  shrinking  areas  of  nomadism,  this  distinction 
between  boundary  zones  and  boundary  lines  may  lead  to  border  incidents, 
or  at  least  account  for  a  gradual  transition  from  a  zone  to  a  line.  It  is 
sufficiently  accurate  to  serve  as  definition. 

There  is  another  difference  between  the  boundary  line  and  the  bound- 
ary zone.  The  latter  is  almost  always  a  feature  which  has  developed  from 
the  conditions  of  contact  between  adjacent  countries.  In  the  few  cases 
where  a  boundary  zone  has  been  determined  by  law,  actually  three  inter- 
nationally recognized  units  exist,  sharply  divided  from  each  other  by 
boundary  lines.  An  example  of  this  is  the  zones  of  the  Pays  de  Gex  and 
of  Haute  Savoie  surrounding  the  Swiss  canton  of  Geneva,  which  are 
outside  of  the  French  customs  boundary  and  subject  to  Swiss  military 
occupation  in  wartime,  though  in  all  other  respects  being  genuine  parts 
of  the  French  republic. 

On  the  other  hand,  a  boundary  line  is  always  a  legally  established  and 
defined  feature,  though  its  legality  may  not  have  found  recognition  in 
international  law.  The  United  States  has  declared  that  it  does  not  recog- 
nize the  incorporation  of  the  three  Raltic  States,  Lithuania,  Latvia,  and 
Estonia,  into  the  Soviet  Union,  nor  does  it  recognize  several  other  bound- 
aries drawn  after  World  War  II.  Nevertheless,  these  boundary  lines  exist 
and  function  as  instituted  by  Soviet  action  and  Soviet  law,  unaffected  by 
international  recognition  or  nonrecognition.  The  boundaries  of  the  Baltic 


THE  NATURE  AND  FUNCTIONS  OF  BOUNDARIES  81 

States  function  today  as  internal,  or  purely  administrative  boundaries,  and 
have  been  changed  in  some  parts. 


TYPES  OF  BOUNDARIES 

We  have,  therefore,  to  distinguish  several  types  of  boundaries:  (1) 
boundaries  that  are  recognized  in  international  law,  as  is  normal  with 
most  boundaries;  (2)  boundaries  that  are  recognized  only  by  some  coun- 
tries, especially  by  both  adjacent  countries,  (a)  This  may  be  the  result 
of  a  shift  of  the  boundary  without  altering  its  legal  character.  The  eastern 
boundary  of  Poland  and  the  northeastern  boundary  of  Rumania  are  such 
boundaries,  (b)  On  the  other  hand,  the  boundaries  of  the  Baltic  countries 
are  regarded  by  the  United  States  as  de  jure  international  boundaries, 
but  are  de  facto  and  according  to  the  legal  concept  of  the  Soviet  Union 
internal  boundaries.  The  practical  effects  of  such  a  nonrecognition  are 
very  restricted,  and  will  pertain  to  passport  procedures,  immigration 
practice,  and  similar  functions.  The  term  "disputed  boundaries"  is  correct 
for  these  boundaries,  but  applies  in  general  usage  rather  to  (3)  de  facto 
boundaries,  the  legality  of  which  is  not  recognized  by  one  of  the  adjacent 
countries.  Parts  of  the  Ecuadorian-Peruvian  boundary  and  of  the  Indian- 
Chinese  boundary  belong  in  this  category.  Often  the  two  adjacent  coun- 
tries claim  two  different  lines  as  correct,  of  which  only  one  exists  de  facto 
(the  disputed  boundary),  while  (4)  the  other  can  be  found  on  maps  but 
has  no  counterpart  in  the  field.  Such  a  fictitious  boundary  is  the  boundary 
between  Germany  and  Poland  as  it  existed  before  1939  and  is  still  re- 
garded by  the  nations  of  the  West  as  legally  valid  until  such  time  as  a 
peace  treaty  may  change  it  (Fig.  4-1).  Most  American  maps  show  this 
line  and  designate  the  territory  west  of  it  as  under  Polish  administration. 
On  Polish  maps,  and  on  maps  printed  in  countries  which  are  emotionally 
less  involved  in  this  conflict,  this  boundary  has  disappeared. 

Both  the  de  facto  and  the  claimed  boundary  may  be  recognized  or  not 
by  third  powers,  strengthening  thereby  the  legal  and  political  position 
of  one  of  the  contesting  countries,  but  not  immediately  affecting  the 
material  situation.  In  Trieste  from  1946  to  1954  there  existed  three  bound- 
ary lines  (cf.  Fig.  2-2).  One,  claimed  by  Italy,  incorporated  the  whole 
territory  of  Trieste,  including  areas  administered  by  Yugoslavia.  De  facto 
this  is  an  internal  boundary.  Another  part  of  the  boundary  line  divided 
Yugoslav  territory  from  that  administered  by  Great  Britain  and  the  United 
States,  though  claimed  by  Italy.  A  third  boundary,  which  separated  the 


82 


THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 


EAST 

GERMANY 


'<oVa  V  V   #«>%/*****%■' i 


50 100  Km 


a  ^H 


24 


m. 


Fig.  4-1.  The  Boundaries  of  Poland  since  World  War  II. 


same  territory  from  Italy,  was  a  de  facto  boundary,  but  with  a  different 
status  in  the  eyes  of  the  different  powers.  The  occupying  powers  regarded 
it  as  a  fully  recognized  international  boundary.  The  Yugoslavs  agreed  to 
its  designation  as  an  international  boundary,  but  claimed  it  as  their  own 
and  not  that  of  a  Free  Territory  of  Trieste.  The  Italians  finally  regarded 
it  at  best  as  a  temporary  de  facto  demarcation  line  which  has  no  legal 
standing  as  boundary.  In  the  same  category  belongs  the  38th  parallel  in 
Korea  which  served  as  a  de  facto  boundary  from  1945  to  1951;  all  par- 
ticipants regarded  it  as  a  temporary  solution,  an  armistice  line  rather 
than  a  boundary. 

Claimed  (fictitious)  boundaries  are  also  those  on  the  Antarctic  con- 
tinent; 2  but  it  can  hardly  be  said  that  they  run  through  a  foreign  territory 
as  all  claims  are  equally  theoretical  and  none  fully  recognized  internation- 
ally ( Fig.  4-2 ) .  The  United  States  has  not  recognized  the  claims  of  several 
states  on  Antarctic  territories.  Great  Britain,  Australia,  New  Zealand, 
France,  Norway,  Argentina,  and  Chile  have  made  such  territorial  claims 

2  Cf.  L.  Martin,  "The  Antarctic  Sphere  of  Interest,"  H.  W.  Weigert  and  V.  Stefans- 
son,  eds.,  New  Compass  of  the  World  (New  York,  1949),  pp.  61  ff.  (71-73). 


THE  NATURE  AND  FUNCTIONS  OF  BOUNDARIES      83 

and  fixed  by  proclamation  exact  boundary  lines.  Those  of  the  five  first- 
named  countries  have  been  mutually  recognized,  while  in  the  case  of  the 
Palmer  Peninsula,  where  Britain,  Argentina,  and  Chile  are  established, 
these  three  countries  continue  to  dispute  their  mutual  claims. 

These  Antarctic  sectors  have  their  counterpart  in  the  Arctic.  Here,  how- 
ever, it  is  not  the  discovery  of  uninhabited  territories  which  forms  the 
basis  of  claims,  but  an  extension  of  the  areas  of  the  countries  surrounding 
the  Arctic  Sea.  Though  in  a  different  form  and  more  or  less  assertive, 
Canada,  Denmark,  Norway,  and  the  Soviet  Union  rely  on  the  "sector 
principle"  (cf.  Fig.  5-4,  p.  126).  Only  the  Soviet  Union  went  so  far  as  to 
fix  the  boundaries  of  its  Polar  possessions  in  accordance  with  the  sector 
principle,  by  decree  of  April  15,  1926. 3 

The  sector  principle  serves  as  a  good  illustration  of  the  intimate  relation- 
ship which  exists,  particularly  in  the  realm  of  boundary  problems,  be- 
tween basic  concepts  of  international  law  and  political  geography.  The 
student  of  political  geography  is  concerned  mainly  with  the  definition 
of  the  area  between  the  base  line  which  links  the  meridians  of  longitude 
marking  the  limits  of  its  frontiers  in  the  east  and  in  the  west,  and  which 
extends  as  far  north  as  the  final  intersection  of  those  meridians  in  the 
Pole:  this  is  the  geographical  definition  of  the  sector  principle  as  primarily 
a  geometric  method  to  measure  the  geographical  extent  of  a  sovereignty 
claim  in  the  Arctic.  To  understand  the  legal,  or  quasi-legal,  foundation 
of  this  principle  one  has  to  turn  to  basic  principles  of  international  law. 
The  sector  principle,  legally,  is  an  expression  of  basic  concepts  of  sover- 
eignty resting  firmly  upon  geographical  foundations,  or  supposed  to  rest 
on  them.  Sovereignty  over  a  territory  presupposes  normally  that  a  state 
exercises  authority  over  certain  territory.  Normally,  this  authority  is  estab- 
lished and  maintained  by  what  is  called  "effective  occupation."  In  exten- 
sion of  this  principle,  attempts  have  been  made  to  establish  sovereignty 
by  contiguity;  this  concept  has  been  used  mainly  to  determine  if  islands 
which  are  relatively  close  to  the  shores  of  a  country  should  belong  to  the 
country  controlling  the  shores  in  virtue  of  their  geographical  location. 
The  sector  principle  represents  a  further  expansion  of  the  contiguity 
principle. 

If  one  realizes  these  features  of  international  law  which  are  at  the 
bottom  of  the  sector  principle,  it  is  not  difficult  to  find  that  a  basic  dif- 
ference exists  between  the  Arctic  and  the  Antarctic  in  regard  to  the  sector 

3  E.  Plischke,  "Sovereignty  and  Imperialism  in  the  Polar  Regions,"  reprinted  in 
H.  and  M.  Sprout,  Foundations  of  National  Power,  2nd  ed.  (N.  Y.,  1951),  pp.  727, 
729. 


Fig.  4-2.  Antarctic  Claims. 


84 


THE  NATURE  AND  FUNCTIONS  OF  BOUNDARIES  85 

principle;  for  this  principle,  as  an  extension  of  the  contiguity  concept, 
does  not  make  sense  in  the  South  Polar  regions. 

Here  we  deal  with  a  continent  detached  from  any  other  and  separated 
from  other  lands  by  broad  expanses  of  water  from  the  territories  that  are 
acknowledged  to  belong  to  claimant  states.  "Inasmuch  as  there  are  no 
'contiguous'  territories  extending  into  this  area,  as  Canada  and  Russia 
extend  into  the  Arctic,  these  Antarctic  sector  claims  must  rest  upon  a 
different  theory  from  the  Arctic  principle."  4 

The  United  States  has  subscribed  always  to  the  theory  that  "effective 
occupation"  is  required  as  the  basis  of  a  claim  of  sovereignty  over  newly- 
discovered  lands,  including  Polar  lands.5  The  technological  achievements 
of  our  times  lend  support  to  the  concept  that  the  principle  of  international 
law  under  which  "effective  occupation"  is  a  prerequisite  for  the  acquisition 
of  "title"  over  a  territory  merits  validity  also  in  the  Arctic  and  Antarctic. 

THE  FUNCTIONS  OF  BOUNDARIES 

There  is  a  real  gradation  in  the  effective  functioning  of  a  boundary 
from  serving  as  an  almost  absolute  barrier  through  several  stages  to  the 
purely  theoretical  function  of  a  claimed  boundary.  The  barrier  function 
is  best  exemplified  in  the  Iron  Curtain  around  the  countries  of  the  Soviet 
Bloc  at  present.  It  is,  however,  not  an  absolute  barrier.  There  are  not  only 
those  refugees  who  escape;  more  important  is  that  trade  is  being  carried 
on  all  the  time.  There  are  sensitive  areas  where  countries  bordering  the 
Iron  Curtain  are  not  completely  identified  with  either  East  or  West,  such 
as  Finland  and  Iran.  A  big  hole  appears  where  until  1955  the  Iron  Curtain 
crossed  Austria,  a  country  that  had  retained  its  unity  despite  the  fact 
that  parts  of  it  lay  behind  and  others  in  front  of  the  Iron  Curtain.  It  thus 
appears  that  the  Iron  Curtain  has  not  achieved,  and,  at  least  as  long  as 
peace  can  be  preserved,  is  unlikely  to  achieve  the  strength  of  the  walls 
which  Japan  and  China  erected  around  their  borders  from  the  seventeenth 
to  the  nineteenth  century.  We  know,  however,  that  even  at  the  time  of 
the  most  perfect  seclusion  of  Japan,  the  tiny  Dutch  foothold  in  the  harbor 
of  Nagasaki  was  sufficient  to  maintain  a  certain  osmotic  exchange.  Japa- 
nese artistic  influences  filtered  into  the  West,  as  did  Western  medical 
knowledge  into  Japan,  to  mention  only  two  important  features. 

4  Hackworth,  Digest  of  International  Law  (1940),  p.  461.  The  official  positions  of 
Argentina  and  Chile  are  in  conflict  with  the  above  and  their  claims  are  based  in  part 
on  the  contiguity  concept;  at  best,  a  geological  but  certainly  not  a  geographical  con- 
tiguity can  be  claimed  in  this  case. 

5  Miller.  "Rights  Over  the  Arctic,"  Foreign  Affairs  (1925),  pp.  49-51. 


86  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

Boundaries  are  often  closed  for  certain  functions  only.  Barriers  to 
immigration  or  to  the  import  of  merchandise  are  more  frequent  than 
those  to  emigration  and  exports.  The  closing  of  the  American  border  to 
liquors  in  the  era  of  Prohibition  is  well  remembered.  Newspapers  and 
books  are  sometimes  excluded  from  crossing  a  border.  Such  barriers  may 
be  absolute  or  may  be  partial.  Under  the  so-called  quota  system  a  certain 
merchandise  may  be  allowed  across  the  border  in  specified  quantities  only, 
or  prohibitive  customs  may  reduce  the  quantities  which  would  come  in 
without  such  taxation.  The  high  value  of  a  currency  may  act  as  a  deter- 
rent. It  is  obvious  that  the  restricting  influence  of  all  such  factors  can 
vary  in  wide  degrees.  The  system  of  immigration  quotas  in  the  United 
States  is  based  on  a  general  principle,  the  proportion  of  resident  alien-born 
from  each  country  at  a  given  date.  In  practice,  this  law  opens  the  borders 
to  any  average  Englishman,  but  closes  it  to  the  majority  of  prospective 
immigrants  from  many  other  countries  such  as  China  or  Italy. 

Though  almost  all  degrees  of  exclusion  may  be  found,  there  is  no 
international  boundary  which  does  not  constitute  an  obstacle  of  some 
kind.  Legal  systems  differ  even  between  countries  very  close  to  each  other 
in  sentiment  aid  practice.  No  two  countries  have  the  same  system  of 
taxation.  Unavoidably,  the  teaching  of  history  in  schools  has  slightly 
different  emphases.  Allegiance  is  required  to  a  specific  flag.  The  American- 
Canadian  boundary  is  an  example  of  such  a  minimum  function  which 
still,  in  many  tangible  and  intangible  ways,  has  a  separating  effect. 

It  is  obvious  that  such  international  boundaries  do  not  have  a  much 
different  function  than  do  certain  internal  boundaries,  especially  those 
between  the  states  of  the  United  States.  In  other  countries  internal  bound- 
aries may  mean  less.  In  the  United  States  state  boundaries  have  stronger 
separating  functions  than  county  boundaries  or  city  boundaries;  still  less 
important  is  the  function  of  boundaries  of  townships  or  city  wards. 
However,  there  is  no  boundary  which  is  not  separating  some  feature, 
no  boundary  without  function. 

The  modern  state  is  characterized  by  the  great  number  of  functions 
it  exercises,  functions  distinguishing  it  in  all  its  constitutional  forms  from 
its  earlier  predecessors,  especially  the  feudal  state.  This  multiplicity  and 
the  complexity  of  organization  related  to  it  is  one  of  several  reasons  why 
accurate,  linear  boundaries  become  necessary,  and  are  now  the  rule. 


THE  NATURE  AND  FUNCTIONS  OF  BOUNDARIES      87 

BORDER  ZONES 

The  status  of  border  territories  has  been  more  and  more  defined  and 
transitional  border  zones  have  almost  disappeared  from  the  map,  even 
in  South  America  where  they  were  the  rule  along  the  borders  only  fifty 
years  ago.  Also  the  number  of  undemarcated  boundaries  is  rapidly  shrink- 
ing, though  as  a  matter  of  course  not  as  fast  as  the  number  of  undelimited 
boundaries  or  unallocated  territories.  The  only  sizeable  land  area  under 
this  last  category  would  be— and  this  only  for  official  American  opinion— 
the  Antarctic  continent.  There  are  a  few  more  undelimited  areas  in  the 
Arabian  peninsula,  along  the  land  boundaries  of  China,  and  those  of 
Thailand.  Not  quite  in  the  same  category  are  disputed  areas,  such  as 
Kashmir,  the  southwestern  corner  of  Ecuador,  and  a  few  others  of  minor 
importance  at  present.  Among  the  undemarcated  boundaries  are  several 
African  boundaries,  such  as  most  boundaries  of  Ethiopia,  or  the  boundary 
between  the  French  and  Spanish  Sahara,  Libya,  and  others. 

Even  if  a  boundary  has  been  agreed  upon,  the  old  separating  zone 
must  not  disappear.  There  is  still  the  little  known  and  little  exploited 
forest  between  Brazil  and  its  neighbors  to  the  north  and  west,  the  desert 
between  Libya  and  its  neighbors,  and  the  high  mountain  belt  between 
Burma  and  its  neighbors.  It  is,  however,  the  agreed  boundary  line,  and 
no  longer  an  unpassable  belt  of  forest,  desert,  or  swamps  which  minimizes 
the  danger  of  border  clashes.  An  interesting  example  is  offered  by  the 
Rub'al  Khali  (Fig.  4-3),  the  Empty  Quarter  of  Southern  Arabia,  which 
serves  as  frontier  or  boundary  zone  between  Saudi  Arabia  to  the  north 
and  west  and  the  Trucial  emirates,  Oman  and  Hadramaut,  to  the  east 
and  south.  In  1913  Turkey  and  Great  Britain  agreed  to  a  boundary 
through  unknown  areas.  This  boundary  still  appears  on  some  maps, 
though  the  outbreak  of  World  War  I  prevented  ratification  of  the  treaty 
and  Saudi  Arabia  never  recognized  its  validity.  This  was  still  no  matter 
of  concern  for  Britain  until  Bertrand  Thomas  in  1927  and  St.  John  B. 
Philby  the  following  year  crossed  this  desert.  From  this  moment  the 
dwindling  barrier  character  of  the  Rub'al  Khali  became  obvious.  How- 
ever, Saudi  Arabia  felt  strong  enough  to  press  its  claim  only  after  it  had 
granted  oil  concessions  to  the  Arabian-American  Oil  Company  ( Aramco ) , 
hoping  thereby  to  force  the  United  States  to  back  her  claims.  The  recent 
conflict  over  the  Buraima  oasis  between  Saudi  Arabia  and  Oman,  the 
claims  of  both  the  tiny  but  oil-rich  Sheikhdom  of  Qatar  and  of  Saudi 
Arabia  have  highlighted  a  developing  dangerous  situation  in  this  desert 


88 


THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 


^ia^lo***  V'  Baraimi 


SiiP  Dl      A  RA8IA 


Fig.  4-3.  Rub'al  Khali,  "The  Empty  Quarter"  of  Southern  Arabia. 

area.6  Without  the  establishment  of  boundary  lines,. bloody  conflicts  may 
become  more  and  more  frequent. 

A  similar  situation  existed  in  the  north  of  the  Arabian  peninsula.  Since 
World  War  I  boundaries  have  gradually  been  established  and  largely 
demarcated  between  Saudi  Arabia  and  its  neighbors,  Jordan,  Iraq,  and 
Kuwait.  In  two  places,  where  no  agreement  could  be  reached,  two  neutral 
zones  between  Saudi  Arabia  on  the  one  side  and  Iraq  and  Kuwait  on  the 
other  are  policed  by  both  adjacent  powers.  They  are  themselves  bordered 
by  definite  lines  and  owe  their  continued  existence  not  as  much  to  their 
barrier  character  as  to  rivalry  and  jealousy.  They  are  more  closely  related 
to  buffer  states  or  condominiums  than  to  frontier  zones  of  a  primitive 
character.  A  much  discussed  area  is  the  tribal  area  or  the  frontier  region 
of  the  North  West  Frontier,  an  area  included  by  the  international  bound- 
ary between  Afghanistan  and  Pakistan  and  the  administrative  boundary 


6  A.  Melamid,  "Political  Geography  of  Trucial  Oman  and  Qatar,"  Geographic  Re- 
view, Vol.  11,  No.  3  (April,  1953);  and  the  same  author:  "Oil  and  the  Evolution  of 
Boundaries  in  Eastern  Arabia,"  ibid.,  Vol.  11,  No.  4  (April,  1954). 


THE  NATURE  AND  FUNCTIONS  OF  BOUNDARIES  89 

of  the  North  West  Frontier  Province  proper,  the  Durand  line  of  1893. 
The  British  gave  only  a  minimum  of  administration  to  this  area.7 

The  only  other  surviving  zones  lie  between  India  and  Tibet  in  the  high 
uninhabited  mountains  of  Himalaya  and  Karakorum,  and  between  China 
and  Burma  in  the  broken  plateaus  inhabited  by  Shan  tribes.  Both  adjacent 
countries  claim  sovereignty  over  each  of  these  zones  and  some  day  some 
delimitation  will  have  to  take  place.  During  the  nineteenth  century  many 
countries  agreed  to  draw  boundary  lines  through  such  unexplored  bound- 
ary zones.  Such  boundaries  were  drawn  on  the  conference  table  and 
either  used  assumed  physical  features  or  geometrical  lines  as  boundary 
lines.  Assumed  physical  features  were  selected  as  a  rule  in  South  America, 
geometrical  lines  more  frequently  between  European  colonies  in  Africa 
and  occasionally  in  other  continents.  This  method  has  been  denounced 
as  artificial  and  arbitrary.  However,  it  is  often  unavoidable.  Geographers 
refer  to  this  type  of  boundaries  as  "antecedent"  boundaries,  antecedent 
to  actual  occupation  or  even  exploration.8  It  cannot  be  denied  that  this 
method  resulted  in  especially  unfortunate  results  in  regions  of  densely 
settled,  somewhat  advanced  civilizations,  though  the  area  might  have 
been  unexplored  by  Europeans.  Some  of  the  boundaries  of  Thailand  and 
of  the  western  Sudan  belong  in  this  category.  This  applies  only  to  densely 
populated  areas,  and  fortunately  they  were  a  minority.  One  should, 
furthermore,  keep  in  mind  that  in  most  of  these  instances  the  only 
alternative  was  either  to  defer  delimitation  until  demarcation  on  the 
ground  should  become  possible,  or  to  designate  some  suspected  physical 
feature.  To  defer  delimitation  would  actually  mean  to  wait  until  interest 
in  the  hitherto  unknown  area  materialized  and  friction  evolved.  This  way 
has  rarely  been  selected,  and  where  it  has,  results  were  unfortunate. 

UNDEFINED  BOUNDARIES 

The  history  of  the  boundaries  of  Afghanistan  throughout  most  of  the 
nineteenth  century  is  an  example  of  frictions  which  a  not  clearly  defined 
boundary  line  may  cause.  The  Russian-Afghan-British-Indian  relations 
were  in  a  state  of  nearly  open  conflict  throughout  the  second  half  of 
the  nineteenth  century;  the  temporary  weakness  of  Russia  and  world-wide 
political  activity  enabled  a  settlement  of  the  boundary  conflict  in  the 

7  There  is  a  large  literature  on  this  area  starting  with  G.  N.  Curzon  of  Kedleston, 
Frontiers  (Oxford,  1907).  The  latest  review  is  by  J.  W.  Spain,  "Pakistan's  North  West 
Frontier,"  The  Middle  East  Journal,  Vol.  8,  No.  1  (1954),  pp,  27-40. 

8  R.  Hartshorne,  "Suggestions  on  the  Terminology  of  Political  Boundaries,"  abstract, 
Annals  of  the  Association  of  American  Geography,  Vol.  26  (1936),  p.  56. 


90  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

eleventh  hour.  However,  the  solution  along  the  Afghan-British-Indian 
boundary  proved  workable  only  as  long  as  the  British  power  in  India 
stood  on  solid  foundations.  Instead  of  the  usual  boundary  line  to  which 
all  state  functions  extend,  three  lines  were  established.  This  resulted  in 
the  creation  of  two  boundary  zones  of  which  only  that  adjacent  to  India 
was  administered  effectively.  Even  here  not  all  state  functions  were 
exerted.  Another  zone  adjacent  to  Afghanistan  was  not  administered  but 
was  supervised  by  the  British.  Since  Pakistan  has  taken  the  place  of  India, 
Afghanistan  has  voiced  more  vocal  claims  than  ever  before  for  this  area, 
which  is  inhabited  by  Pushtu-speaking  tribes;  Pushtu  is  the  language  of 
the  ruling  group  of  Afghanistan  (cf.  Fig.  3-1,  p.  59 ).9 

The  undefined  boundary  between  Ethiopia  and  Italian  Somaliland 
opened  the  road  to  the  war  of  1935,  when  both  parties  advanced  into 
no  man's  land  and  clashed  at  Ual-Ual. 

DEMARCATION  OF  BOUNDARIES 

Designation  of  unexplored  physical  features  such  as  water  partings, 
mountain  crests,  and  rivers,  has  caused  many  conflicts  in  South  America. 
The  Argentine-Chilean  conflict  was  ended  by  arbitration  of  the  British 
monarch  who  assigned  the  disputed  territories  to  the  contestants.  The 
conflict  area  was  described  in  detail  by  the  British  geographer-states- 
man 10  who  was  engaged  in  investigating  the  topographic  background. 
In  this  case  it  had  been  agreed  that  the  boundary  should  follow  "the 
highest  crest  which  may  divide  the  waters"  (Fig.  4-4).  Unfortunately, 
and  unknown  at  the  time  of  the  agreement,  the  highest  crest  and  the 
water-parting  do  not  coincide  for  a  distance  of  many  hundreds  of  miles. 
The  final  award  found  a  compromise  solution. 

A  river  was  designated  as  the  boundary  between  French  Guiana  and 
Brazil,  another,  the  St.  Croix  river,  between  Maine  and  the  adjacent 
provinces  of  Canada,  both  rivers  no  longer  identifiable  12  when  settlement 
advanced  and  fixation  of  the  boundary  became  necessary.  The  nonexistent 
"northwestern  corner  of  the  Lake  of  the  Woods"  on  the  Minnesota-Canada 
boundary  (Fig.  4-5)  required  at  least  sixteen  additional  conventions12 
until  all  the  questions  were  resolved  which  arose  from  the  original  peace 
treaty  formulation. 

9  See  p.  394. 

10  Holdich,  op.  cit. 

11  Jones,  op.  cit.,  p.  200. 

12  Boggs,  International  Boundaries,  pp.  47-50. 


THE  NATURE  AND  FUNCTIONS  OF  BOUNDARIES 


91 


Argentine  Claim 

Chilean  Claim          ___^ 
Boundary  Fixed       

0_  100  200 300  Mi 


Fig.  4-4.  The  Argentine-Chilean  Boundary. 

On  the  other  hand,  none  of  the  geometrical  lines  in  Africa  has  led  to 
serious  conflicts.  It  was  possible  in  several  cases  to  create  a  satisfactory 
boundary  by  means  of  exchange  of  territory  and  other  adjustments.  The 
Congo  State  (cf.  Fig.  7-6,  p.  186)  originally  established  as  a  quadrangle, 
at  present  has  a  river  boundary  with  French  Central  Africa,  rivers  and 
lakes  as  boundaries  with  most  of  the  British  areas,  and  very  irregular 
boundaries  with  the  Portuguese  possessions,  the  latter  created  by  ex- 
change of  territories.13 

Because  each  boundary  is  a  result  of  human  selection   and  action, 


13  Ibid.,  p.  186, 


92 


THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 


MANITOBA): 
MINNESOTA 


Fig.  4-5.  The  Minnesota-Canada  Boundary:  Large  inset  shows  location  of  Lake  of 
the  Woods,  as  used  at  Paris  1782-83.  The  lake  in  its  true  position  is  cross-hatched. 
After  Boggs,  International  Boundaries. 

boundary  lines  are  always  artificial  throughout.14  A  boundary  between 
states  can  exist  only  where  and  if  man  establishes  a  boundary.  Boundary- 
making  is  done  generally  in  several  steps,  which  Stephen  B.  Jones  15 
distinguishes  as  delimitation  and  demarcation.  Some  authors  16  distin- 
guish three  steps :  ( 1 )  allocation  of  territory  in  general  terms,  ( 2 )  delim- 
itation, and  (3)  demarcation.  Only  demarcation,  though  actually  only 
the  last  step,  will  be  considered  here.  This  is  the  work  of  the  surveyor 
in  the  field,  directed  by  a  commission  composed  of  the  diplomatic  repre- 
sentatives of  the  two  states  concerned,  sometimes  accompanied  or  even 
headed  by  one  or  several  neutrals.  The  agreement  which  has  been  made 

14  Maull,  op.  cit.,  p.  143,  was  apparently  the  first  to  stress  this  point. 

15  Op.  cit.,  p.  5. 

16Boggs,  International  Boundaries;  and  A.  Hall,  "Boundaries  in  International  Rela- 
tions," in  G.  E.  Pearcy  and  R.  H.  Fifield,  World  Political  Geography  (New  York. 
1948),  pp.  521-524. 


THE  NATURE  AND  FUNCTIONS  OF  BOUNDARIES  93 

at  some  conference  table  as  to  the  site  of  the  boundary  has  to  be  trans- 
ferred into  the  landscape.  Whoever  has  observed  the  slow,  painstaking 
work  of  a  surveyor  fixing  the  limits  of  private  property,  will  not  be  sur- 
prised to  learn  that  demarcation  of  state  boundaries  takes  months  or  even 
years,  not  counting  delays  due  to  disagreement.  Mountains  may  be 
unscalable,  but  they  are  generally  less  difficult  to  demarcate  than  water- 
boundaries.  A  meandering  river  with  its  continuously  shifting  banks  and 
changing  channel  is  a  much  more  difficult  problem.  Even  a  stream  con- 
fined by  rocks  to  a  definite  channel  poses  demarcation  problems.  Bound- 
ary markers  can  not  be  put  in  the  middle  of  a  stream,  but  must  be  set  on 
the  banks  and  serve  only  as  indicators  from  which  to  look  for  the  actual 
boundary.  Thousands  of  soundings  had  to  be  made  to  determine  the 
thalweg  of  the  St.  Croix  river  on  a  short  stretch.17  Decisions  of  a  peace 
conference  or  boundary  conference  to  use  villages  as  boundaries  may 
sound  very  simple.  This  may  result,  however,  in  dividing  the  adjoining 
fields  of  a  single  proprietor  or  in  a  boundary  with  many  protruding 
corners  or  irrational  vagaries. 

Generally  boundaries  have  been  demarcated  by  carefully  surveyed 
intervisible  markers.  In  the  once  valueless,  now  oil-rich  but  featureless 
desert  in  Arabia  behind  the  town  of  Kuwait  the  desert  is  strewn  with  tar 
barrels  deposited  by  sheiks  as  local  landmarks.18  On  some  boundaries, 
where  roads  or  railroads  cross  them,  roadblocks  are  not  uncommon. 
Sometimes  a  path  is  cut  through  forest  and  bush,  a  grass  strip  left  between 
fields,  or  even  a  fence  erected  along  the  whole  length  of  a  boundary.  This 
is  usually  regarded  as  a  last  resort,  if  for  no  other  reason  than  because 
of  the  high  cost  of  erection  and  maintenance.  The  Great  Chinese  Wall 
and  the  Roman  Limes  are  unrivaled  today.  The  so-called  Teggart  Wall 
on  the  northern  border  of  Palestine,  an  electrically  laden  wire  fence,  was 
a  last  attempt  by  the  British  to  keep  undesired  intruders  out.  This  was 
due  to  the  explosive  situation  in  the  last  years  of  the  mandate.  Such 
fences,  only  shorter  ones,  have  been  erected  where  boundaries  cut  through 
towns,  such  as  through  Italian  Fiume  and  its  Yugoslav  suburb  Susak 
before  1940,  today  reunited  as  Rijeka,  or  even  along  the  United  States 
boundary  with  Mexico  through  the  city  of  Laredo.  The  minefields  along 
large  stretches  of  the  "Iron  Curtain"  are  less  visible  but  more  vicious 
barriers. 

All  these  devices,  however,  follow  predetermined  boundaries.  They 
make  the  boundary  visible,  but  do  not  establish  it.  Demarcation  is  the 

17  Jones,  op.  cit.,  p.  117. 

18  The  Economist,  March  28,  1953,  p.  882. 


94  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

legitimate  process  to  make  a  boundary  visible.  Sometimes  demarcation 
follows  allocation  of  territory  and  its  more  detailed  delimitation  on  the 
conference  table  as  soon  as  possible.  That  is  often  the  case  after  wars 
when  territories  are  shifted  from  one  sovereignty  to  another.  Hartshorne  19 
speaks  of  superimposed  boundaries  and  contrasts  them  with  antecedent 
boundaries  which  were  established  long  before  the  land  was  actually 
taken  possession  of,  or  even  before  it  was  known. 

"NATURAL"  AND  "ARTIFICIAL"  BOUNDARIES 

Many  political  geographers  have  fought  against  the  popular  distinction 
between  artificial  and  natural  boundaries.20  The  latter  are  supposed  to 
follow  natural  features  such  as  mountain  ranges,  rivers,  or  deserts,  the 
artificial  ones  being  created  by  man  without  regard  for  physical  features. 
Actually  all  boundaries  are  made  by  man.  Whether  or  not  the  boundary 
followed  or  could  follow  a  natural  feature  depended  on  many  different 
circumstances.  It  has  been  suggested  that  such  boundaries  should  rather  be 
called  "naturally  marked"  21  or  "borrowed  from  nature"  (naturentlehnt) ,22 
They  are  often  opposed  to  straight-line  boundaries.  The  cause  for  the 
selection  of  straight-line  boundaries  may  be  ignorance  of  the  topograph- 
ical features,  as  is  true  of  many  of  the  claimed  boundaries  in  the  Antarctic 
continent.  In  other  instances,  such  features  as  linguistic  affinities,  popular 
loyalties,  or  existence  of  communication  lines,  seemed  far  more  important 
than  the  course  of  a  river  or  a  mountain  crest.  There  is  little  reason  to 
call  this  latter  type  more  artificial  than  a  diplomatically  selected  mountain 
boundary  which  perhaps  cut  off  alpine  pastures  from  the  villages  which 
used  them.  This  happened  when  the  Austro-Italian  border  was  drawn 
after  World  War  I  separating  German-speaking  South  Tyrol  from  North 
Tyrol;  and  it  was  claimed  that  the  coincidence  of  a  high  mountain 
crest  with  a  parting  of  waters  and  strategic  favorable  circumstances  made 
it  a  perfect  "natural"  border.  The  same  happened  in  the  Carpathians 
between  Poland  and  Czechoslovakia  and  a  similar  situation  was  described 
for  an  old  established  border,  that  following  the  Pyrenees.23 

Interest  in  boundary  problems  as  a  geographical  problem  was  first 

19  "Geography  and  Political  Boundaries  in  Upper  Silesia,"  loc.  cit. 

20  Solch,  op.  cit.;  Hartshorne,  "Suggestions  on  the  Terminology  of  Political  Bound- 
aries," loc.  cit.;  Jones,  op.  cit.,  pp.  7-8. 

21  D.  Whittlesey,  The  Earth  and  the  State  (New  York,  1944),  p.  5. 

22  R.   Sieger,  "Zur  politisch-geographischen  Terminologie,"  Zeitschrijt  der  Gesell- 
schaft  fiir  Erdkunde,  Vol.  52,  No.  3  (Berlin,  1917-18). 

23  D.  Whittlesey,  "Trans-Pyrenean  Spain,  The  Val  d'Arran,"  Scottish  Geographical 
Magazine,  Vol.  49  ( 1933),  pp.  217-228. 


THE  NATURE  AND  FUNCTIONS  OF  BOUNDARIES      95 

awakened  by  Ratzel.  Living  and  writing  in  Germany,  he  knew  thoroughly 
the  problems  and  artificial  character  of  the  boundaries  of  the  German 
states.  Indeed,  they  were  to  a  large  degree  a  product  of  the  Napoleonic 
period  and  their  delimitation  was  mainly  a  result  of  considerations  which 
had  nothing  to  do  with  geography  or  historical  tradition,  but  aimed  to 
give  every  prince  a  state  of  carefully  balanced  size  and  taxable  income. 
Nevertheless,  these  artificial  boundaries  have  disappeared  only  since 
World  War  II  in  many  parts  of  Germany  and  some  still  survive.24 

Often  the  term  artificial  boundary  is  used  as  the  equivalent  for  bad 
boundary.  Jones  25  has  shown  in  a  very  great  number  of  examples  that 
any  boundary  may  be  good  or  bad  according  to  the  difficulties  inherent 
in  the  type  of  boundary  as  well  as  in  the  circumstances  of  the  time.  While 
mountain  ranges  are  generally  regarded  as  good  boundaries,  the  inter- 
national commission  appointed  to  fix  the  boundary  between  Turkey  and 
Iraq  in  1921  agreed  unanimously  that  the  Jabel  Sin  jar  should  be  allocated 
as  a  unit.26  This  mountain  chain  in  a  semidesert  is  practically  a  group 
of  oases  on  both  sides  of  the  range,  remote  from  any  other  permanent 
settlement. 

In  conclusion,  "there  are  no  intrinsically  good  or  bad  boundaries  ...  all 
international  border  lands  are  potentially  critical.  A  boundary  may  be 
stable  at  one  time,  unstable  at  another,  without  a  change  of  a  hairsbreadth 
in  its  position."  27 

BOUNDARIES  MARKED  BY  PHYSICAL  FEATURES 

Because  of  the  widespread  preference  for  such  naturally  marked  bound- 
aries, those  physical  features  shall  be  briefly  reviewed  which  are  most 
often  quoted  and  used  for  such  purposes,  especially  mountain  crests, 
water  partings,  and  rivers.  Mountain  crest  boundaries  exist  in  all  con- 
tinents with  the  exception  of  Australia.  It  has  been  noticed  that  the 
perhaps  oldest  group  of  political  boundaries,  the  boundaries  of  the  his- 
torical eighteen  provinces  of  China,  in  general  follow  mountain  crests 
or  traverse  other  sparsely  populated  zones;  only  occasionally  do  they 
utilize  rivers. 2S  But  even  in  New  Guinea  the  boundarv  between  the 
Australian  territory  of  Papua  and  the  trusteeship  territory,  the  former 

24  F.  Metz,  Siidwestdeutsche  Grenzen  (Remagen,  1951). 

25  Op.  cit.,  pp.  121-162. 

26  Ibid.,  p.  98. 

27  Ibid.,  p.  3. 

28  H.  J.  Wood,  "The  Far  East,"  in  W.  G.  East  and  O.  H.  K.  Spate,  The  Changing 
Map  of  Asia  ( London,  1950 ) ,  p.  268. 


96  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

German  New  Guinea,  was  placed  on  the  central  mountain  axis  of  the 
island.  Where  a  sharp  crest  exists  and  where  it  coincides  with  the  parting 
of  waters,  such  a  boundary  line  is  of  the  most  stable  and  satisfactory 
type.  The  mountains  often  have  formed  an  uninhabited  and  mostly  unused 
zone  between  two  countries  long  before  a  boundary  line  was  established. 
One  of  the  few  surviving  examples  of  such  a  state  exists  in  the  Himalayas 
between  India  and  China.  Frequently  mountain  valleys  and  high  pastures 
have  been  slowly  included  in  the  economic  system  of  the  adjacent  areas 
and  the  actual  boundary  line  developed  gradually.  Such  boundary  lines 
do  not  necessarily  coincide  with  the  crestline— it  may  be  practical  to  reach 
high  pastures  by  means  of  a  mountain-crossing  pass;  or,  people  living  on 
one  side  may  have  used,  and  be  entitled  to,  areas  on  both  sides  of  the 
crest;  or,  a  common  economic  way  of  life  may  bring  together  a  population 
living  on  both  sides  of  the  crestline.  The  usual  small-scale  map  is  mis- 
leading because  it  cannot  show  small  but  significant  deviations.  Thus  the 
Pyrenees,  often  cited  as  a  perfect  mountain  boundary  of  this  type, 
separate  France  and  Spain  only  on  part  of  the  actual  boundary.29 

In  mountain  ridges  which  lack  sharp,  continuous  crests,  it  can  be  shown 
that  the  boundary  line  is  usually  a  late  development,  developing  from 
an  original  frontier  zone.  The  mountains  may  not  even  be  the  primary 
frontier  zone,  which  may  be  dense  forests.30  Bohemia,  often  called  a 
mountain  fortress,  is  surrounded  by  rather  low  mountains,  mostly  short 
ridges  with  gaps  between  them.  One  of  them,  the  Ore  mountain  ( Erzge- 
birge  to  the  Germans,  Krusne  Hory  to  the  Czechs),  is  devoid  of  the 
original  forest  cover,  and  it  appears  that  the  very  old  boundary  deviates 
almost  throughout  its  whole  length  from  the  rather  sharp  divide  between 
the  gentle  north-western  Saxonian  slope  and  the  steep  escarpment  leading 
into  the  interior  of  Bohemia.  The  boundary  is  located  on  the  gentle  north- 
western slope,  though  it  is  evident  that  this  slope  constitutes  the  lesser 
obstacle  to  penetration.  However,  it  was  not  the  desire  for  tillable  land 
or  political  expansion  which  brought  man  onto  the  mountain,  but  the 
quest  for  precious  minerals.  Mining  attracted  settlers  into  the  mountains 
and  the  need  of  timber  and  charcoal  for  the  mines  is  responsible  for  the 
disappearance  of  the  forests.  The  boundary  line,  however,  became  stabi- 
lized in  general  where  the  miners  from  both  sides  met. 

In  general,  it  still  holds  true  that  virgin  forests,  uninhabited  mountain 

29  Whittlesey,  "Trans-Pyrenean  Spain,  The  Val  d'Arran,"  loc.  cit. 

30  At  least  one  recent  author  denies  entirely  the  protective  function  of  the  Bohemian 
mountain  rim,  J.  A.  Steers,  "The  Middle  People:  Resettlement  in  Czechoslovakia," 
Geographic  Journal,  Vol.  102  ( January,  1949 ) . 


THE  NATURE  AND  FUNCTIONS  OF  BOUNDARIES  97 

ridges,  swamps  and  deserts  fulfill  their  function  as  natural  boundary 
zones,  as,  for  instance,  is  still  the  case  in  the  undefined  deep  boundary 
zones  which  separate  the  border  of  Sinkiang  from  Tibet  and  the  similarly 
inaccessible  1800-mile-long  border  which  separates  Tibet  from  India, 
Sikkim  and  Bhutan.  At  the  same  time,  it  is  true  for  many  areas  that  the 
intensification  of  agriculture,  technological  progress,  the  improvement  of 
communication  systems,  and  the  spreading  population  have  narrowed 
the  extent  of  no  man's  land  serving  as  boundary  zones.  Forests  have  been 
cut  down  or  taken  under  management.  Regular  policing  has  extended 
far  into  the  largest  desert  of  the  world,  the  Sahara.  Permanent  meteoro- 
logical and  a  chain  of  radar  stations  are  ringing  the  Polar  regions.  Swamps 
have  been  drained,  as  happened  to  the  Bourtanger  Moor  on  the  German- 
Dutch  border.  Under  a  five-year  plan  presented  in  1952,  the  U.S.S.R. 
intends  to  drain  about  25,000  square  miles,  or  an  area  roughly  the  size 
of  Connecticut,  Massachusetts  and  Delaware  combined,  in  the  Pripet 
marshes  in  Byelorussia  and  the  Ukraine,  with  the  goal  of  adding  about 
nine  million  acres  of  fertile  peat  soil  lands  to  the  Soviet  cultivated  area. 

RIVERS  AS  BOUNDARIES 

In  many  cases  preference  has  been  expressed  for  rivers  as  boundaries. 
Boggs  31  and  Jones  32  have  shown  the  difficulties  arising  from  the  use  of 
rivers  as  boundaries.  Most  boundary  conflicts  between  states  of  the  United 
States  have  been  caused  by  river  boundaries.33  Also  the  international 
boundary  disagreements  of  the  United  States  have  been  concerned  with 
rivers.  There  was  the  question  concerning  the  course  of  the  St.  Croix  river 
which  had  been  designated  as  the  boundary  between  the  state  of  Maine 
and  the  Canadian  Maritime  Provinces,  and  there  are  the  continuing  prob- 
lems which  the  continuously  shifting  Rio  Grande  has  created  at  the 
Mexican  border  since  it  was  adopted  as  boundary  in  1848.  An  agreement 
in  1934  settled  most,  but  not  all  controversial  points.  The  conflict  over 
the  use  of  the  waters  of  the  Colorado  river  by  California  and  diminution 
of  their  volume  for  Mexico  is  not  strictly  a  boundary  problem. 

In  Kashmir,  a  similar  controversy  lent  strength  to  the  claim  of  Pakistan 
for  a  boundary  which  would  give  to  that  country  control  over  waters  it 
needs  for  irrigation.  This  type  of  conflict  becomes  a  genuine  boundary 
case  if  a  river  which  is  necessary  for  irrigation  is  used  as  a  boundary 

31  International  Boundaries,  pp.  179-182. 

32  Op.  cit.,  pp.  108  ff. 

33  See  map,  Jones,  op.  cit.,  p.  109. 


' I 


Fig.  4-6.  The  Bratislava  Bridgehead  on  the  Danube. 


Fig.  4-7.  The  Louisiana  Extension  on  the  Mouth  of  the  Mississippi. 


98 


THE  NATURE  AND  FUNCTIONS  OF  BOUNDARIES  99 

line,  as  is  true  of  the  Jordan  river  between  Syria  and  Israel.  To  the  use 
of  waterways  for  navigation,  irrigation,  and  flood  control,  recently  has 
been  added  their  use  as  a  source  for  power.  In  all  these  cases  not  only 
the  management  of  the  river  along  the  border,  but  that  of  tributaries  far 
away  may  influence  its  usability. 

It  appears  that  rivers  are  less  manageable  as  boundaries  than  any  other 
feature.  Any  tampering  with  them,  even  the  construction  of  badly  needed 
flood  dykes,  influences  the  opposite,  foreign  shore  and  possibly  affects 
areas  farther  downstream.  To  leave  a  river  alone  is  not  practicable,  because 
of  the  general  tendency  of  rivers  to  undercut  portions  of  their  banks,  silt 
up  channels,  or  shift  their  beds.  Only  common  management  in  a  friendly 
spirit  can  minimize  the  frictions  resulting  from  the  separating  boundary 
function. 

Actually,  rivers  unite  rather  than  divide  the  opposite  banks.  River  basins 
are  essentially  units  and  the  unifying  function  of  a  drainage  basin  is  in 
many  cases  indistinguishably  joined  to  the  separating  function  of  the 
divides.  Historians  and  political  geographers  have  long  recognized  the 
essential  unity  of  the  Paris  basin  of  the  Seine  river,  of  Bohemia,  of  the 
Danubian  basin,  the  Vistula  basin,  the  Amazon  basin,  the  Gangetic  plain, 
and  many  others.  On  the  other  hand,  where  river  boundaries  have  been 
established  there  is  frequently  the  desire  to  create  at  least  a  bridgehead 
on  the  most  important  crossing  point.  The  Bratislava  bridgehead  on  the 
Danube  (Fig.  4-6)  and  the  Louisiana  extension  across  the  lower  Missis- 
sippi (Fig.  4-7)  may  suffice  as  examples. 

Many  attempts  have  been  made  to  unite  entire  river  basins  for  the 
purpose  of  flood  control,  irrigation,  and  power  development.  Bv  the 
inclusion  of  the  whole  river  basin  in  such  a  scheme,  these  projects  differ 
basically  from  international  river  regulation  agreements  for  navigable 
rivers  such  as  have  been  devised  for  the  Danube  and  the  Rhine.  In  this 
context  the  spectacular  success  of  the  Tennessee  Valley  Authority  ( TV  A ) 
project  comes  to  mind  (cf.  Fig.  18-3,  p.  579).  But  the  achievements  of  the 
TVA  reveal  both  the  potentials  and  limitations  of  this  type  of  river  basin 
control  project,  especially  if  one  tries  to  use  the  TVA  example  as  a  yard- 
stick for  other  river  and  flood  control  plans.  In  the  case  of  the  TVA  it  was 
possible  to  overcome  gradually  the  reluctance  of  a  number  of  states 
within  the  Union  which  gave  up  some  of  their  state  rights  in  favor  of  the 
interstate  agency. 

Since  the  TVA  came  into  existence,  dozens  of  'TV  As"  have  been 
planned  within  the  United  States  and  abroad;  scores  of  missions  from 
foreign  countries  have  studied  the  American  TVA  and  American  experts 


100  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

have  explored  the  possibilities  for  similar  projects  in  foreign  countries. 
However,  while  the  economic  advantages  achieved  by  the  TVA  in  many 
respects  are  impressive,  no  other  attempt  to  imitate  this  project  has  been 
successful  and  political  obstacles  have  proved  too  formidable  to  be  over- 
come. This  is  primarily  true  for  projects  in  internationally  disputed  areas 
as  along  the  Jordan  river  or  in  the  area  of  the  principal  rivers  of  the 
Indus  Basin  which  provide  water  for  irrigation  in  Pakistan  and  originate 
in,  or  flow  across  India,  Kashmir,  or  Jammu.34  In  spite  of  the  often- 
expressed  hope  that  the  execution  of  such  river  basin  projects  would 
result  in  significant  economic  advantages  to  all  contestant  powers  and 
would  pave  the  way  for  political  reconciliation,  political  issues  have 
maintained  their  priority  as  a  separating  factor.  It  appears  that  such 
ambitious  projects  can  be  undertaken  successfully  only  if  the  international 
situation  between  the  interested  nations  is  on  a  firm  and  peaceful  basis. 
Even  within  the  United  States  objections  to  unification  raised  by  local 
and  special  interests  have  proved  to  be  a  most  formidable  obstacle. 
Neither  the  Missouri  Basin  nor  the  Columbia  Basin  Authority  have 
developed  beyond  the  blueprint  stage.  Most  of  the  international  projects 
have  not  even  entered  the  blueprint  stage,  and  some  of  them,  though 
entirely  sound  and  important  from  the  economic  point  of  view,  are  at 
this  time  not  more  than  speculations  in  the  harsh  light  of  political 
realities. 

OCEANIC  BOUNDARIES 

A  special  type  of  water  boundaries  are  the  oceanic  boundaries  of  all 
states  bordering  the  sea.  The  shoreline  is  often  regarded,  especially  for 
statistical  purposes,  as  the  boundary  of  a  country.  The  definition  of  the 
shoreline  may  lead  to  difficulties,  particularly  on  low  coasts  adjacent  to 
shallow  seas  with  high  tides.  Should  the  mean  water  level,  the  average 
low-water  mark,  or  the  mark  at  spring  tide  be  regarded  as  the  boundary? 
Different  countries  have  claimed  each  of  these  lines.  More  important, 
however,  is  the  claim  of  most  nations  to  sovereignty  over  their  territorial 
waters.  This  is  a  zone  of  water  several  miles  wide.  A  majority  of  countries, 
among  them  countries  which  in  1950  registered  four-fifths  of  all  com- 
mercial shipping  tonnage,  claim  a  zone  three  miles  wide.35  Another  almost 
10  per  cent  of  commercial  tonnage  was  registered  in  Scandinavian  coun- 
tries which  claim  a  four-mile  limit.  The  remaining  countries  are  by  no 

34  See  p.  97. 

35  S.  W.  Boggs,  "National  Claims  in  Adjacent  Seas,"  Geographical  Review,  Vol.  41 
(1951),  p.  202. 


THE  NATURE  AND  FUNCTIONS  OF  BOUNDARIES  101 

means  negligible,  as  they  count  among  them  the  Soviet  Union  which 
claims  a  twelve-mile  belt. 

The  United  States,  on  September  28,  1945,  proclaimed  that  it  would 
regard  the  "natural  resources  of  the  subsoil  and  the  sea  bed  of  the  con- 
tinental shelf  beneath  the  high  seas  but  contiguous  to  the  coasts  of  the 
United  States  as  appertaining  to  the  United  States,  subject  to  its  juris- 
diction and  control"  (cf.  Fig.  5-3,  p.  125).  This  assertion  of  rights,  which 
is  based  on  the  geological  unity  of  the  shelf  and  the  adjacent  land,  re- 
ceived legislative  sanction  by  the  Outer  Continental  Shelf  Act  of  August 
7,  1953. 36  A  number  of  states,  most  of  them  in  the  Americas  and  around 
the  Persian  Gulf,  have  followed  the  American  example  and  claimed  cer- 
tain rights  over  the  continental  shelf.  Australia  followed  suit  in  1953,  by 
proclaiming  sovereignty  over  her  entire  continental  shelf  reaching  in 
places  more  than  two  hundred  miles  off  her  coast.  The  Japanese  were  thus 
precluded  from  fishing  for  pearl  shell  in  the  waters  off  Australia's  northern 
coast.  Countries  such  as  Chile,  Peru,  San  Salvador,  and  Honduras  have 
substituted  for  the  claim  to  the  continental  shelf  a  claim  to  a  two  hundred- 
mile  zone.  All  these  countries  border  the  Pacific  Ocean— except  the  north 
coast  of  Honduras— and  the  continental  shelf  under  any  definition  would 
be  of  insignificant  width.  Many  countries  have  established  special  purpose 
claims  of  different  width,  ranging  from  the  six  miles  claimed  for  customs 
and  coastal  defense  by  Poland,  to  a  security  zone  of  at  least  three  hundred 
nautical  miles  around  the  Americas  proclaimed  by  the  Consultative  Meet- 
ing of  Foreign  Ministers  of  the  American  Republics  at  Panama  on  October 
3,  1939. 37  The  present  situation  is  confusing  and  gives  rise  to  international 
conflicts  in  many  oceanic  boundary  areas.  The  International  Law  Com- 
mittee of  the  United  Nations  is  therefore  attempting  to  clarify  the  prob- 
lems involved  by  emphasizing  that  a  coastal  nation  exercises  sovereignty 
over  the  continental  shelf,  but  subject  to  the  principle  of  the  freedom 
of  the  seas. 

In  reviewing  such  claims,  boundary  lines  emerge  which  can  not  be 
demarcated  but  which  are  nonetheless  real.  Boggs  has  shown  3S  that  except 
in  the  rare  instance  of  a  straight  coastline,  it  is  not  easy  to  be  definite 
as  to  where  a  line  should  be  drawn.  Bays,39  islands  and  rocks,  even  curva- 

36  See  Boggs,  "National  Claims  in  Adjacent  Seas,"  loc.  cit.,  pp.  185-209. 

37  Department  of  State  Bulletin,  Vol.  1  (1939),  pp.  331-333. 

38  In  several  publications,  among  them  in  International  Boundaries,  pp.  178-85, 
and  "Delimitation  of  Seaward  Areas  under  National  Jurisdiction,"  The  American 
Journal  of  International  Law,  Vol.  45  (April,  1951),  pp.  240-266. 

39  Boggs,  "National  Claims  in  Adjacent  Seas,"  loc.  cit.;  and  A.  L.  Shalowitz,  "The 
Concept  of  a  Bay  as  Inland  Waters,"  The  Journal,  Coast  and  Geodetic  Survey,  Depart- 
ment of  Commerce,  No.  5  (June,  1953),  pp.  92-99. 


102  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

tures  of  the  coastline  justify  different  points  of  view.  If  two  islands 
of  different  sovereignty  are  closer  together  than  six  miles,  the  definition  of 
the  median  line  is  by  no  means  simple.  Even  an  interior  boundary,  such 
as  that  in  Lake  Michigan  between  Michigan  and  Wisconsin,  took  long- 
drawn  litigation  and  investigation  and  finally  a  decision  of  the  Supreme 
Court  in  1936  to  define  the  line.  Presumably  this  boundary  had  been  well 
described  in  preceding  legal  acts  which  were,  however,  shown  capable 
of  different  interpretation  under  the  actual  conditions  of  a  complicated 
coastline.  The  situation  is  particularly  difficult  if  two  adjacent  countries 
claim  a  different  width  of  their  territorial  waters.  Boggs  has  tried  success- 
fully to  develop  methods  to  find  the  best  line.40  Whether  these  will  be 
adopted  in  international  law  seems  questionable,  at  least  as  long  as  the 
present  tension  remains. 

Even  less  clear  is  where  the  continental  shelf  ends.  The  usual  definition 
of  the  continental  shelf  as  the  area  less  than  a  hundred  fathoms  deep 
and  adjacent  to  dry  land  is  only  a  rough  approximation.  In  some  cases, 
such  as  the  cited  example  of  Chile,  the  slope  of  coastal  mountains  is 
continued  below  the  ocean  surface  and  there  is,  geographically,  no  con- 
tinental shelf.  In  other  cases,  the  gradual  slope  may  reach  much  farther 
than  the  hundred-fathom  line  before  the  sharp  declivity  of  the  continental 
slope  starts.  Rarely  will  continental  slope  and  continental  shelf  join  in 
such  a  sharp  break  that  it  could  be  called  a  line.  Even  the  determination 
of  the  hundred-fathom  line,  though  possible  with  modern  means  of  echo 
soundings,  would  be  a  tedious  job.  We  do  not  even  know  how  stable 
this  line  is. 

DIVIDING  LINES 

A  review  of  maps  shows  that  all  these  various  lines  have  seldom  been 
mapped.  Occasionally,  however,  we  find  simple  lines,  often  geometrical 
lines,  dividing  sovereignties  over  islands  or  in  narrow  seas.  Most  of  these 
lines  are  used  as  a  convenience  by  the  cartographer.  Some,  however, 
have  or  have  had  international  legal  meaning,  such  as  the  line  separating 
Alaska  from  Siberia  (Fig.  4-8),  the  line  dividing  the  islands  belonging  to 
Indonesia  and  the  Philippines,  or  the  now  obsolete  but  famous  dividing 
line  of  the  Papal  decision  and  the  Treaty  of  Tordesillas  between  the 
Spanish  and  Portuguese  overseas  empires.  The  Alaska-Siberian  boundary 
was  established  by  the  purchase  treaty  of  1867,  by  which  the  United 
States  acquired  Alaska.  It  consists  of  two  straight  lines  joining  at  an 
obtuse  angle  in  Bering  Strait.  The  north-south  aligned  part  follows  the 

40  Boggs,  "Delimitations  of  Seaward  Areas  Under  National  Jurisdiction,"  loc.  cit. 


THE  NATURE  AND  FUNCTIONS  OF  BOUNDARIES 


103 


Fig.  4-8.  The  Geometrical  Line  as  Boundary:  Alaska-Siberia. 


meridian  168°  58'  5"  west  of  Greenwich  and  is  not  problematic.  The 
northeast-southwest  aligned  part  connects  the  southern  terminus  of  this 
line  in  65°  30'  northern  latitude  with  a  point  about  halfway  between  the 
westernmost  of  the  Aleutian  Islands  and  the  Soviet  Komandorskie  Islands 
in  54  degrees  north  latitude,  170  degrees  east  longitude.  It  never  was 
agreed  whether  this  line  is  part  of  a  great-circle  line  or  a  rhumb  line, 
probably  because  no  practical  dispute  arose.  It  was  adopted  as  part  of 
the  defense  perimeter  of  the  Americas  at  the  conference  in  Rio  de  Janeiro 
in  1947  and  was  defined  there  as  a  rhumb  line.41  This  Alaskan-Siberian 
boundary  line  appears  on  many  maps  not  as  a  true  political  boundary, 
which  it  is,  but  as  part  of  the  International  Date  Line.  This  is  the  line 
where  ships— and  presumably  airplanes— crossing  the  Pacific  Ocean  west- 
ward skip  a  whole  day,  or  if  bound  eastward,  start  the  past  twenty-four 

41  The  Treaty  was  published  and  the  pertinent  article  4  is  most  accessible  in  F.  O. 
Wilcox  and  T.  V.  Kalijarvi,  Recent  American  Foreign  Policy  (New  York,  1952),  p.  210. 


104  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

hours  over  again.  This  line  follows  the  180°  meridian  except  in  this  area 
and  east  of  New  Zealand,  where  it  deviates  eastward  to  include  several 
island  groups. 

GEOMETRICAL  BOUNDARIES 

It  is  no  accident  that  where  geometrical  lines  have  been  established  as 
boundary  lines,  lines  of  the  geographical  grid  were  preferred.  They  are 
the  easiest  to  establish.  Other  geometrical  lines  exist  but  are  rare.  The 
boundary  between  California  and  Nevada  from  Lake  Tahoe  to  the 
Colorado  near  Mohave  city,  and  that  between  Arizona  and  Mexico  from 
the  Colorado  to  Nogales  are  straight  lines  but  not  geographical  grid  lines 
and  as  such  are  rather  exceptional.  Still  less  common  are  curves,  such  as 
the  parts  of  a  small  circle  which  separates  Delaware  from  Pennsylvania, 
and  that  which  limited  the  former  German,  later  Japanese  concession  of 
Kiaochao  (Tsingtao). 

It  is  too  little  realized  that  many  of  the  winding  boundaries  shown  on 
our  small-scale  maps  are  often  a  series  of  very  short,  straight  lines.  This 
may  surprise  many  people,  because  we  are  inclined  to  regard  straight 
lines  in  the  countryside  as  unnatural.  We  expect  rivers  to  be  winding, 
coasts  to  have  bays  and  promontories,  and  the  edges  of  natural  forests 
to  be  far  from  straight.  However,  new  boundaries  are  often  agreed  upon 
at  a  conference  table  by  attributing  towns  and  villages  to  different  sover- 
eignties. These  local  boundaries  are  often  boundaries  between  fields  and, 
as  often  as  not,  are  straight  lines.42  In  other  cases  a  winding  line  is  divided 
by  the  surveying  field  party  into  short  straight  stretches  to  make  it 
practicable. 

In  Africa  and  between  the  states  of  the  United  States  straight  lines 
originally  were  nothing  more  than  temporary  demarcation  lines.  In  the 
United  States  such  boundaries  have  often  degenerated  into  exclusively 
administrative  lines.  Different  laws,  especially  different  state  tax  systems, 
liquor  laws,  and  so  on,  keep  them  in  the  consciousness  of  their  citizens. 
In  a  few  instances  they  have  won  emotional  values  comparable  to  Euro- 
pean boundaries— the  Mason-Dixon  line  and,  internationally,  the  49th 

42  Only  one  interesting  illustration  will  be  mentioned  to  show  the  interplay  of  man- 
made  features  and  natural  features  and  their  influence  upon  local  boundaries.  In 
eastern  and  southeastern  Wisconsin  "in  general  the  small  rectangular"  woodlot  is  pre- 
dominant, following  the  lines  the  surveyor  has  drawn  dividing  the  quadrangle.  But  in 
central  Wisconsin  "the  rectangular  land  survey  shows  only  rarely  in  the  present  wood- 
land cover.  .  .  .  Slope  and  rock  outcrop  are  much  more  critical  in  aligning  the  woodland 
location."  L.  Durand,  Jr.,  and  K.  Bertrand,  "Forest  and  Woodland  of  Wisconsin," 
Geographical  Review,  Vol.  45  (1935),  p.  270. 


THE  NATURE  AND  FUNCTIONS  OF  BOUNDARIES  105 

parallel.  Eisenhower  has  denounced  the  shopworn  use  of  the  slogan  of 
the  "unfortified  boundary."  He  did  not  intend,  thereby,  to  minimize  the 
value  of  this  boundary,  nor  would  it  be  possible  or  desirable  to  erase 
the  connotation  of  pride  in  this  boundary  from  the  American  conscious- 
ness. Americans,  who  are  often  impatient  of  geometrical  boundaries  in 
other  continents,  are  often  unaware  that  forty-seven  of  their  states  43  have 
such  geometrical  boundaries  and  that  disputes  between  the  states  over 
such  boundaries  have  been  far  less  frequent  than,  especially,  those  over 
river  boundaries  (Fig.  4-9  ).44 

The  straight  line  has  definite  advantages  over  a  winding  line  that 
follows  some  physiogeographic  feature.  This  occurs  in  deserts,  where  land 
values  are  practically  nil.  It  is  very  expensive  and  difficult,  if  not  outright 
dangerous,  to  follow  some  winding  hill  range  or  dry  wadi  bed.  It  may 
be  quite  simple  to  draw  a  straight  line.  A  curious  incident  was  settled 
in  1952  between  Italy  and  Switzerland.  The  boundary  at  one  place  in 
the  high  mountains  crossed  a  glacier.  Demarcation  by  stones  on  the  glacier 
was  possible,  but  the  moving  glacier  continuously  displaced  these  bound- 
ary markers.  Finally  a  straight  line  was  adopted  which  needed  for  fixation 
only  two  intervisible  markers  on  the  firm  rock  on  both  sides  of  the 
glacier.45 

This  does  not  imply  that  geometrical  boundaries  are  always  and  every- 
where preferable.  Apart  from  other  problems  they  are  not  even  always 
easy  to  demarcate.  The  49th  parallel  is  a  ready  example,  especially  as  its 
demarcation  was  undertaken  in  a  spirit  of  good  will  and  neighbor liness. 
A  parallel  is,  however,  a  curve  and  as  such  not  very  convenient  in  the 
field.  Instead  of  following  such  a  curved  line,  the  boundary  commission 
followed  the  sensible  procedure  of  fixing  only  the  boundary  markers  in 
the  astronomically  correct  position  on  the  parallel  and  drawing  straight 
lines  between  them.  It  is  easily  recognizable  that  such  straight  lines  are 
the  chords  of  an  arc  and  shorten  not  only  the  distance  but  cut  off  small 
pieces  of  land  actually  north  of  the  49th  parallel.46  Jones  has  shown  that 
the  area  involved  is  not  large  but  neither  is  it  negligible.47  Probably  not 
very  often  can  such  a  spirit  of  compromise  be  expected. 

43  South  Carolina  is  the  only  exception. 

44  See  Jones,  op.  cit.,  p.  109. 

45  Convention  of  Martigny,  July  4,  1952. 

46  Jones,  op.  cit.,  p.  154. 

47  Ibid.,  p.  157. 


c 
o 


a 

s 

3 
O 

'a 
o 


o 


0) 


J3 


to 
0) 


W5 

c 

v 

i 


3 


s- 

d 

c 

3 

o 
cq 

qS 
■4 

o 


106 


THE  NATURE  AND  FUNCTIONS  OF  BOUNDARIES     107 
BOUNDARY  CHANGES 

An  unfortunate  quality  of  political  boundaries  is  that  they  are  so 
difficult  to  change.  The  longer  a  boundary  exists  the  less  flexible  become 
economic  ties  of  the  frontier  regions  to  their  respective  hinterland.  Admin- 
istrative practices  and  legal  systems  become  ingrained  in  the  life  of  almost 
every  person,  as  in  the  case  of  inheritance  or  marriage  laws  and  customs. 
Emotional  values  and  questions  of  prestige  are  added.  Still  it  is  not  clear 
why  boundaries  should  remain  unchanged  while  man  and  all  his  insti- 
tutions change.  It  has  been  shown  48  that  there  are,  indeed,  occasions 
when  a  boundary  becomes  obsolescent,  loses  part  or  all  of  its  functions 
and  its  international  status.  Such  was  the  case  when  Italian  and  German 
princely  states  joined  to  make  a  unified  or  federal  state.  Created  as  prop- 
erty boundaries  of  feudal  powers,  these  boundaries  crisscrossed  the  land- 
scape in  such  an  irrational  way,  especially  in  Germany,  that  they  could 
not  fulfill  their  function  in  a  modern  state.  They  degenerated  until  after 
World  War  II  they  lost  all  meaning  and  were  no  longer  a  serious  obstacle 
for  the  redrawing  of  the  internal  German  map.49  Only  Bavaria  remained 
mainly  within  its  prewar  boundaries.  However,  such  a  change  of  inter- 
national boundaries  is  rare  without  resort  to  war.  It  is  somewhat  more 
often  found  in  internal  boundaries,  where  a  peaceful  change  in  the  loca- 
tion of  a  boundary  can  often  be  effected.  The  growth  of  modern  metro- 
politan cities  shows  the  frequency  of  such  changes  on  a  low  level,  but 
also  the  obstacles  which  exist  even  on  this  level. 

International  boundary  changes  are  usually  effected  by  violence.  The 
38th  parallel  in  Korea  is  the  most  recent  example  of  an  unsatisfactory 
boundary  resulting  from  war.  However,  when  the  38th  parallel  boundary 
was  established,  following  World  War  II,  it  was  not  thought  of  as  a 
boundary  line  of  any  duration,  but  as  a  momentary  demarcation  line 
between  the  occupying  forces  of  the  Soviet  Union  advancing  from  the 
north,  and  the  Americans  advancing  from  the  south.50  No  natural  features 
would  have  commanded  immediate  recognition  as  outstanding,  as  shown 
by  the  widely  divergent  suggestions  for  regional  boundaries  which  had 
been  advanced  under  peaceful  conditions.51  Old  administrative  boundary 

48  Fischer,  loc.  cit.,  p.  208. 

49  Metz,  loc.  cit. 

50  S.  McCune,  "The  Thirty-eighth  Parallel  in  Korea,"  World  Politics,  Vol.  1  (Janu- 
ary, 1949),  pp.  223-225. 

51  Review  of  such  suggestions,  especially  by  the  Russian  geographer  V.  T.  Zaichikov 
in  1947  and  the  German  geographer  H.  Lautensach  in  1942,  by  S.  McCune,  "Geo- 
graphic Regions  in  Korea,"  Geographical  Review,  Vol.  39  (October  21,  1949),  pp. 
658-660. 


108 


THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 


Fig.  4-10.  Germany  Divided  (1955). 


lines  offered  another  alternative.  In  the  light  of  experience  in  Europe  it 
must  be  doubted  whether  any  of  these  alternatives  was  preferable.  The 
Oder-Neisse  line  follows  physical  features.  The  boundary  line  between 
Eastern  and  Western  Germany  follows  pre-existing  administrative  bound- 
aries. Both  have  been  denounced  vehemently.  If  so  far  they  have  not 
played  the  same  unfortunate  role  as  the  38th  parallel,  this  is  hardly  to 
be  attributed  to  intrinsic  merits  but  rather  to  political  circumstances. 
The  violation  of  the  38th  parallel  could  be  expected  to  lead  to  a  conflict 
between  minor  powers,  South  and  North  Korea  only;  as  a  matter  of  fact, 
despite  the  activities  of  the  United  Nations,  and  especially  of  American 
troops,  the  war  remained  localized.  In  Germany  any  clash  over  the  bound- 
ary would  have  meant  the  immediate  outbreak  of  another  World  War. 
It  is  to  be  regretted  that  immediate  independent  negotiations  for  a 
boundary  to  replace  the  temporary  38th  parallel  demarcation  line,  were 
not  entered  into.  Again  the  German  example  is  significant  (Fig.  4-10). 
Despite  all  protests  there  is  a  strong  possibility  that  the  Oder-Neisse  line 
will  remain  for  some  time.  Even  more  ominous  is  the  gradual  crystalliza- 
tion of  the  boundary  between  the  two  Germanies.  The  establishment  and 
development  of  two  totally  different  economic,  ideological,  and  political 


THE  NATURE  AND  FUNCTIONS  OF  BOUNDARIES     109 

systems  can  no  longer  be  extinquished  by  a  political  act  of  reunion.  The 
allegiance  of  the  two  economies  to  two  different  systems  is  leading  to 
many  competing  developments  in  industry  and  elsewhere  which  can  not 
coexist  in  a  reunited  Germany.  A  youth  educated  and  indoctrinated  by  a 
Communist  regime  will  speak  a  language  which,  despite  the  same  vocab- 
ulary, will  have  little  meaning  in  the  West.  The  longer  the  boundary  con- 
tinues to  exist  the  more  difficult  it  will  be  to  erase  it. 

It  has  been  suggested  that  it  is  easier  to  change  boundaries  that  have 
not  had  time  to  crystallize— to  become  associated  with  prestige,  historical 
traditions,  or  material  interests.52  Geometrical  lines  as  boundaries  through 
unknown  territory  correspond  best  to  these  conditions.  They  may,  there- 
fore, for  the  purpose  of  a  preliminary  division  fulfill  the  purpose.  Danger 
arises  if  they  are  allowed  to  crystallize  before  a  necessary  adjustment  can 
be  accomplished.  Such  a  danger  line  is  the  boundary  partitioning  the 
Ewe  tribe  in  Africa  between  French  and  British  sovereignty  and  kept 
by  both  powers  despite  all  protests  by  the  Ewes  themselves.  In  the 
same  area,  namely  Togoland  and  the  Gold  Coast,  an  early  adjust- 
ment made  possible  the  reunion  of  two  other  tribes,  the  Dagomba  and 
Mamprusi  in  1946.53 

The  38th  parallel  is  no  longer  used  as  a  boundary  in  Korea.  The  new 
demarcation  line,  the  armistice  line  of  1953,  has  replaced  it  at  least 
temporarily.  This  line  follows  ridges  and  associated  physical  features  for 
large  stretches.  It  is  based  on  the  results  of  the  fighting,  and  has  been 
proved  by  its  history  as  a  strategically  acceptable  boundary.  Who  would 
state,  however,  that  this  one  factor  is  so  preponderant  as  to  make  it  a 
"good"  boundary?  At  least  it  does  not  coincide  with  any  of  the  lines 
suggested  previously. 


54 


52  Fischer,  loc.  cit.,  p.  203. 

53  G.  Padmore,  The  Gold  Coast  Revolution  (London,  1935),  pp.  153-154. 

54  See  McCune,  "The  Thirty-eighth  Parallel  in  Korea,"  loc.  cit. 


CHAPTER 


5 


The  Impact  or  Boundaries 


THE  BOUNDARY  AS  FUNCTION  OF  THE  STATE 

Whether  we  like  it  or  not,  we  are  living  in  a  period  when  the  state 
is  assuming  more  and  more  functions.  Americans,  traditionally,  do  not 
like  it.  Population  increase,  technological  progress,  especially  develop- 
ment of  communications,  progressive  differentiation  and  stratification  of 
social  groups,  increase  of  population  groups  of  proportionally  greater 
mobility,  rising  standards  of  living,  and  need  for  raw  materials  from  all 
over  the  world,  have  combined  to  make  life  more  complicated.  They 
have  forced  more  functions  upon  the  state  because  the  individual  or  even 
the  small  integrated  group  is  no  longer  capable  of  performing  them,  and 
is  also  incapable  of  existing  without  them.  At  the  same  time  people  are 
becoming  more  and  more  conscious  of  the  omnipresence  of  the  state,  its 
functions,  and  its  institutions.  We  have  become  accustomed  to  the  national 
mail  service.  Today  we  write  and  receive  more  Christmas  cards  than  all 
the  correspondence  our  great-grandfathers  had  in  a  whole  year,  or  perhaps 
in  a  lifetime.  We  use  money  coined  and  printed  by  the  government. 
But  in  many  other  respects  we  regard  government  as  irksome  or  as  an 
unavoidable  nuisance. 

Boundaries  are  national  institutions  and  fulfill  functions  that  a  hundred 
or  more  years  ago  were  unthought  of.1  Some  of  the  functions,  such  as 
high  tariffs,  are  asked  for  by  interested  groups  of  the  citizenry.  Others 
are  demanded  by  considerations  of  national  welfare,  such  as  the  exclusion 

1  An  almost  complete  list  of  functions  is  given  by  S.  W.  Boggs,  International  Bound- 
aries (New  York,  1940),  pp.  9-10. 

110 


THE  IMPACT  OF  BOUNDARIES  111 

of  diseased  animals.  Some  functions  are  simply  taken  for  granted,  and  are 
hardly  noticed  by  the  great  majority  of  citizens.  The  average  citizen  is 
little  concerned  with  the  fact  that  on  the  other  side  of  the  border  different 
laws  and  customs  regulate  the  punishment  of  crime,  inheritance  of  prop- 
erty, and  many  other  things.  When  he  attempts  to  cross  a  boundary, 
however,  many  functions  are  felt  and  resented  as  restrictions  of  his  free- 
dom and  independence.  That  a  passport  is  necessary  to  cross  most  bound- 
aries, that  a  tourist  can  take  out  of  a  country  only  certain  items,  and 
similar  boundary  restrictions  are  resented  by  the  average  traveler.  These 
are,  at  least  potentially,  sources  of  friction. 

To  remove  these  boundary  frictions  two  solutions  seem  possible: 
diminution  of  the  functions  of  boundaries  until  they  finally  disappear, 
or  redrawing  of  boundaries.  Theoretically  the  first  way  seems  the  better; 
in  practice,  it  is  the  second  solution  which  is  almost  exclusively  aimed  at. 

We  must  start  with  the  admission  that  the  complete  abolition  of  inter- 
national boundaries  is  a  Utopian  concept  at  present.  Apart  from  practical 
difficulties,  as  long  as  nationalistic  ideologies  are  so  deeply  ingrained  and 
are  still  increasing  in  many  parts  of  the  world,  the  chances  for  "One 
World"  seem  very  remote  indeed.  Realistic  advocates  of  gradual  dimi- 
nution of  boundary  functions  look  to  results  of  their  work  with  satisfaction 
only  if  they  take  a  very  long-range  view.  It  must  be  realized  that  the 
current  trend  of  development  goes  rather  in  the  opposite  direction  and 
it  may  be  that  to  keep  boundaries  functioning  within  traditional  limi- 
tations is  sometimes  beyond  practical  possibilities. 

DIMINISHING  FUNCTIONS  OF  BOUNDARIES 

Still,  it  is  possible  to  draw  a  long  list  of  functions  which  have  been 
suspended  for  the  benefit  of  international  organizations,  thereby  relieving 
international  boundaries  of  some  of  their  functions.  The  most  far-reaching 
undertakings  in  this  respect  are  truly  world-wide  in  purpose,  such  as 
many  of  the  functions  of  separate  committees  of  the  United  Nations. 
Some  of  the  most  successful  of  such  organizations  antedate  the  United 
Nations  and  even  the  League  of  Nations.  The  Red  Cross,  founded  in 
1859,  is  still  outside  the  United  Nations,  as  is  a  late-comer,  the  World 
Council  of  Churches  of  Christ.2  Their  effect  on  boundary  functions  may 
be  small  or  intangible;  however,  the  Red  Cross  has  been  able  to  send 
rapid  help  across  boundaries  in  disaster  areas  without  regard  of  boundary 
restrictions,  and  the  recent  assembly  of  the  Council  enabled  Church  func- 

2  Founded  1948. 


112  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

tionaries  who  would  have  been  excluded  by  law,  to  come  to  the  United 
States.  Some  older  institutions  have  become  special  agencies  of  the  United 
Nations,  such  as  the  Universal  Postal  Union,3  the  International  Court  of 
Justice,4  and  the  International  Labor  Office;  5  but  most  of  these  interna- 
tional organizations  have  originated  as  special  agencies  of  the  United 
Nations.  The  United  Nations  Educational,  Scientific,  and  Cultural  Organi- 
zation, the  Food  and  Agricultural  Organization,  the  International  Mone- 
tary Fund,  and  the  World  Health  Organization  are  the  best  known.6 
Others,  aiming  at  common  standards  in  certain  aspects  of  life,  are  con- 
tinuously added.  Only  recently  a  World  Meteorological  Organization,7 
and  a  few  years  earlier  an  International  Telecommunications  Union,8  have 
been  founded.  These  two  agencies  are  remarkable  because  they  include 
among  their  members  all  states  of  the  Soviet  bloc.9 

Even  where  common  standards  are  accepted  by  several  nations  or  all 
nations  concerned,  the  member  nations  will  often  continue  to  perform 
their  functions  differently.  For  instance,  the  same  standards  adopted  in 
educational  matters  do  not  necessarily  lead  to  the  different  states  admin- 
istering them  similarly.  Yet  such  agreements  gradually  lead  to  the  simpli- 
fication of  functions  which  eventually  are  no  longer  irritating  and  sources 
of  friction  in  their  differences.  Sometimes  the  diminution  of  boundary 
irritations  is  not  always  obvious  in  the  disappearance  of  functions;  their 
effects  are  intangible  but  not  less  real. 

OBSOLESCENCE  OF  BOUNDARIES 

It  seems  easier  to  conclude  international  agreements  between  two  or 
a  few  states  than  to  make  multination  agreements.  Agreements  between 
the  United  States  and  Canada  about  the  utilization  of  the  waters  of  the 
Great  Lakes,  or  between  the  United  States,  Great  Britain,  France,  and  the 
Netherlands  concerning  economic  co-operation  in  the  Caribbean  region 
come  to  mind.  However,  it  should  not  be  overlooked  that  regional  pacts 
may  carry  with  them  the  danger  of  substituting  a  larger  and  stronger  or- 
ganization for  several  smaller  and  weaker  ones.  There  is  the  danger  of 
making  some  boundaries  less  obnoxious  by  strengthening  the  outer  bor- 

3  Founded  1874. 

4  Created  1945  as  successor  to  the  Permanent  Court  of  International  Justice. 

5  Founded  originally  1919,  reorganized  1944,  accepted  into  the  U.N.  1946. 

6  Founded  between  1944  and  1948. 

7  Founded  1951. 

8  Founded  1934. 

9  For  a  complete  list  of  organs,  special  agencies  of  the  U.N.,  and  other  international 
organizations  see  The  Statesman's  Yearbook,  1953. 


THE  IMPACT  OF  BOUNDARIES 


113 


10  Mi 


□  £D 


Fig.  5-1.  The  Saar:  Coal  and  Steel  Industries:  (1)  coal  field;  (2)  steel  mills. 

ders  of  the  regional  organization.  Such  development  occurred  when  the 
continuously  quarreling,  but  rarely  fighting,  small  German  and  Italian 
princely  states  were  replaced  by  a  strong  Germany  and  Italy.  Their  wars 
endangered  Europe  and  finally  the  world.  Similarly,  we  can  discern  that 
the  replacement  of  the  Arab  states  by  a  well-organized  league  would  cer- 
tainly end  the  petty  squabbles  between  them,  but  might  strengthen  them 
for  a  great  war. 

So  far  it  is  easier  to  show  for  internal  than  for  international  relations 
that  obsolescence  of  boundaries  may  be  a  way  of  progress.  The  develop- 
ment of  the  Ruhr  industrial  area  across  the  boundaries  of  the  Prussian 
provinces  of  Westphalia  and  Rhineland  led  to  the  organization  of  the 
Ruhr  Planning  Authority  in  1920. 10  After  Germany's  defeat  in  1945  the 
road  was  open  to  unite  the  two  Prussian  provinces  in  one  state.  Similarly 
two  cities,  the  Free  City  of  Hamburg  and  the  Prussian  city  Altona  were, 
with  several  smaller  communities,  reorganized  as  a  land  (state)  under  the 

10  For  a  detailed  discussion  of  the  Ruhr  as  an  integral  part  of  the  European  economy, 
3  N.  J.  G.  Pounds,  The  Ruhr  ( Bloomington,  Ind.,  1952),  pp.  237-239. 


see 


114  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

Hitler  regime  in  1938,  after  the  boundaries  had  lost  almost  all  sociological 
functions. 

There  are  some  slight  indications  that  the  increasing  interdependence 
between  the  Saar  area  and  France  and  the  old-established  close  cultural 
and  social  connections  between  the  Saar  and  Germany  are  tending  to 
make  the  boundaries  gradually  obsolete  (Fig.  5-1).  Should  these  bound- 
aries lose  further  economic  and  sociological  functions  they  would  be 
reduced  to  political  and  national  ones,  and  a  solution  of  the  vexing  Saar 
problem  may  be  easier. 

UNCONTESTED  BOUNDARIES 

Desirable  as  the  taking-over  of  boundary  functions  by  international 
organizations  may  be,  it  is  largely  a  matter  of  future  developments  and, 
therefore,  still  outside  of  the  field  of  political  geography.  On  the  other 
hand,  political  boundaries  have  been  redrawn  on  a  large  scale  all  the  time, 
mostly  under  pressure  by  the  stronger  country  and  very  rarely  by  mutu- 
ally satisfactory  agreements.  Conquest  is  still  the  main  factor  in  boundary 
changes.  We  have  to  accept  as  a  fact  the  phenomenon  that  there  are 
strong  forces  working  for  change  of  existing  boundaries.  It  is  tragicomic 
that  a  stronger  country  often  justifies  its  expansion  with  the  argument  that 
for  its  own  protection  it  needs  border  areas  belonging  to  a  weaker  neigh- 
bor. If  boundaries  remain  unchanged  this  may  be  caused  by  the  absence 
of  forces  which  work  for  change.  Although  Americans  will  immediately 
be  reminded  of  the  United  States  boundary  with  Canada,  it  should  be 
stressed  that  stability  due  to  absence  of  these  forces  is  rather  the  exception 
than  the  rule.  It  has  been  pointed  out 11  that  the  line  separating  the  United 
States  from  Canada  is  generally  referred  to  as  "the  boundary,"  while  the 
line  separating  this  country  from  Mexico  is  called  "the  border."  It  is  be- 
lieved that  the  distinction  stems  from  the  fact  that  there  has  been  more 
friction  between  the  United  States  and  Mexico  than  with  Canada.  There 
has  also  been  more  lawlessness  on  both  sides  along  the  southern  line, 
which  the  word  border  suggests.  We  may  translate  it  into  our  terminology 
by  saying  that  there  has  been  less  pressure  against  the  invisible  but  rigid 
boundary,  causing  conflicts  and  violation  of  laws,  than  against  the  south- 
ern border,  creating  along  the  latter  a  zone  in  which  the  repercussions  are 
felt. 

«W.  P.  Webb,  The  Great  Frontier  (New  York,  1952),  pp.  2ff. 


THE  IMPACT  OF  BOUNDARIES  115 

BOUNDARIES  UNDER  PRESSURE 

More  significant  than  the  absence  of  forces  is  the  presence  of  conflicting 
forces  which  exert  pressure  against  the  boundary  from  opposite  sides. 
Working  singly,  either  would  tend  to  displace  the  boundary;  operating  in 
opposition,  they  tend  to  neutralize  each  other.  The  attempt  has  been  made 
to  define  international  boundaries  as  the  continuously  changing  line  where 
the  pressure  from  two  adjacent  political  bodies  attains  a  momentary  bal- 
ance.12 Last,  but  not  least,  there  are  strong  forces  at  work  to  preserve 
established  boundaries.  Before  discussing  these  two  types  of  forces,  those 
working  for  change  and  those  working  for  stability,  it  is  necessary  to  point 
out  some  features  of  boundaries  which  are  characteristic  for  a  zone  of 
varying  width  adjacent  to  a  boundary.  This  zone  is  commonly  called  the 
frontier. 

FRONTIER  AND  INTERIOR 

It  has  become  common  usage  to  speak  of  frontiers  or  frontier  zones  in 
two  different  meanings.  One  is  the  frontier  as  a  border  area  without  exact 
delimitations,  usually  preceding  the  delimitation  and  demarcation  of  a 
boundary.  This  use  of  the  term  in  the  designation  of  the  western  frontier 
of  the  United  States  is  well  known.  We  have  seen  in  a  preceding  chapter 
that  this  type  of  frontier  has  almost  disappeared.  We  are  here  concerned 
with  the  second  type  of  frontier:  the  zone  which  extends  inland  from  a 
boundary  line  and  generally  merges  gradually  with  the  interior  of  the 
country.  Small  countries,  of  course,  have  no  interior  in  the  sense  that  there 
is  an  area  where  the  influence  of  the  frontier  is  not  felt  at  all.  However, 
even  in  such  a  tiny  country  as  Israel  the  difference  between  the  frontier 
and  the  interior  is  apparent.  The  inhabitants  of  the  villages  on  the  border 
are  not  only  in  daily  danger  of  life  by  raids  across  the  frontier,  but  they 
also  resent  the  seemingly  unconcerned  behavior  of  the  big-city  dweller. 
However,  measured  by  standards  of  other  countries,  these  same  city 
dwellers  are  acutely  aware  of  boundary  problems,  if  for  no  other  reason 
than  the  space  they  occupy  in  the  daily  news. 

In  large  countries  the  dwellers  of  interior  areas  are  unaware  of  and 
indifferent  to  boundary  problems.  The  Middle  West  of  the  United  States, 
once  the  "frontier"  par  excellence,  has  become  the  prototype  of  a  country 
where  people  do  not  know  anything  of  foreign  countries,  are  not  inter- 
ested in  them,  and  do  not  want  to  have  anything  to  do  with  them.  Appar- 

12  J.  Ancel,  Geographie  des  frontieres  (Paris,  1938). 


116  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

ently  this  type  of  isolationism  is  receding;  it  is  still  enough  of  a  life  force 
to  illustrate  our  point.13 

In  this  connection,  mention  may  be  made  of  the  fact  that  the  very  size 
of  the  country  and  the  basic  difference  of  psychological  attitudes  in  regard 
to  border  problems  between  the  people  of  the  Middle  West  are,  for  in- 
stance, the  people  of  the  Eastern  Seaboard  regions,  account  for  the  fact 
that  "in  the  United  States  the  word  frontier . .  .  becomes  a  concept  with 
such  wide  ramifications  and  so  many  shades  of  meaning  that  it  cannot  be 
wrapped  up  in  a  neat  definition  like  a  word  whose  growth  has  ceased  and 
whose  meaning  has  become  frozen.  It  is  something  that  lives,  moves  geo- 
graphically." 14 

FRONTIER  PSYCHOLOGY 

Willingly  or  not,  people  living  near  a  boundary  have  their  lives  shaped 
by  its  influence  one  way  or  the  other.  In  past  periods  border  provinces 
received  greater  autonomy  because  it  was  impossible  to  defend  them 
against  a  sudden  attack  if  their  authorities  had  not  enough  power  to  do  so 
of  their  own  accord.  There  are  many  examples  where  the  population  of 
a  border  area  was  organized  in  a  permanent  semimilitary  organization, 
called  a  "march"  in  Europe.  The  Cossacks,  along  the  Russian  and  Ukrain- 
ian frontiers,  were  organized  against  Turkey  and  the  Tatars  and  are  per- 
haps the  best  known.  Their  semimilitary  autonomy  survived  to  the 
Bolshevist  revolution.  Austria,  another  medieval  "march,"  has  survived  as 
a  separate  body  politic,  but  its  citizens  are  still  unsure  how  far  they  have 
developed  a  separate  national  awareness.  At  times  they  liked  to  think  of 
themselves  as  Germans  because  of  their  German  language  and  certain 
traditions;  but  every  time  they  come  in  close  contact  with  the  Germans, 
they  feel  vividly  the  differences  in  their  way  of  life.15 

Inhabitants  of  frontier  zones  are  in  many  cases  conscious  of  the  fact 
that  they  live  in  an  exposed  situation.  This  is  not  only  true  in  half-civilized 
environments  such  as  the  Frontier  Province  of  Pakistan  and  Afghanistan, 
but  people  of  Lorraine  and  Alsace  feel  the  neighborhood  of  a  potential 
attacker  very  strongly.  It  is  not  incidental  that  some  of  the  most  national- 
istic, but  also  most  gifted  political  leaders  of  France  came  from  this  politi- 
cally-conscious frontier.  Many  similar  cases  can  be  cited-  One  may  suffice. 

13  See  pp.  21-23. 

14  Webb,  op.  cit.,  pp.  2  ff. 

15  There  exists  a  voluminous  literature  on  this  problem.  See  especially  H.  W.  Wei- 
gert,  Generals  and  Geographers  (New  York,  1942),  pp.  115  ff.,  and  the  book  of  the 
chancellor  Schuschnigg,  Drei  Mai  Osterreich  (Innsbruck,  1938),  written  before 
Hitler's  conquest  of  Austria  in  1938. 


THE  IMPACT  OF  BOUNDARIES  117 

The  population  of  Finnmark  and  Troms,  the  two  northernmost  provinces 
of  Norway,  suffered  most  heavily  from  war  destruction  in  World  War  II 
because  of  their  proximity  to  the  Russian  border.  Now  they  are  more  con- 
scious than  ever  that  they  would  be  the  first  victims  of  a  violent  East-West 
conflict. 


EFFECTS  OF  THE  FRONTIER  ON  ECONOMIC  LIFE 

The  endangered  frontier  situation  is  brought  home  to  people  also  in 
regard  to  their  freedom  of  movement.  Not  only  the  boundary  itself  but 
military  installations  and  regulations  affecting  so-called  defense  areas  re- 
strict this  movement.  This  leads  also  to  restrictions  hampering  the  eco- 
nomic life  of  such  a  region.  Market  towns,  which  normally  would  be  in  the 
center  of  an  agricultural  area,  may  have  a  lopsided  trading  area.  In  gen- 
eral, because  of  boundary  restrictions,  a  city  close  to  a  boundary  will  be 
cut  off  from  "natural,"  that  is,  nearby,  customers  by  the  boundary.  Less 
normal,  but  still  quite  frequent,  is  the  city  that  because  of  differing  prices 
and  money  values  has  a  trading  area  across  the  border  larger  than  in  its 
own  country.  During  the  last  few  years  we  have  seen  how  in  Berlin  people 
from  the  western  sectors  of  the  city  flocked  into  East  Berlin  because  of  the 
lower  exchange  value  of  the  East  Mark;  16  later  this  trend  was  reversed 
when  wares  became  scarce  and  the  people  from  the  Soviet  sector  came 
into  West  Berlin  to  purchase  things  unavailable  in  the  East.  Eventually 
movement  in  both  directions  slackened  because  of  the  political  difficulties 
put  in  its  way  X1  (cf.  Fig.  3-3,  p.  64).  On  a  smaller,  but  instructive  scale 
it  was  shown  that  new  businesses  concentrated  at  the  points  of  crossing 
from  one  to  the  other  zone,  while  at  the  same  time  established  businesses 
—barbers,  grocers,  cobblers,  and  others— located  along  the  boundary  but 
away  from  the  crossings,  had  to  close  up  because  many  of  their  customers 
could  not  reach  them  across  the  street,  or  at  least  could  not  pay  the  prices 
in  a  different  currency.18  What  happened,  dramatically,  in  Berlin  within  a 
short  period  and  in  a  small  area  is  but  an  illustration  of  what  occurs  in  one 
or  the  other  form  along  almost  any  boundary.  Even  if  economic  conditions 
on  both  sides  of  a  boundary  are  approximately  equal,  prices  on  the  same 
level,  and  boundary  formalities  at  a  minimum,  the  unavoidable  formali- 
ties will  influence  the  mutual  movement. 

16  P.    Scholler,    "Stadtgeographische    Probleme    des    geteilten    Berlin,"    Erdkunde, 
Vol.  7,  No.  1  (1953),  p.  6. 

17  G.  W.  S.  Robinson,  "West  Berlin,  The  Geography  of  an  Exclave,"  Geographical 
Review,  Vol.  43  (October,  1953),  p.  549. 

18  Scholler,  loc.  cit. 


118  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

Movement  occurs  not  only  in  the  form  of  trade,  but  also  in  commuting 
from  the  place  of  residence  to  the  place  of  work.  Some  boundaries  make 
commuting  of  this  kind  impossible  or  difficult;  others  invite  it.  Mexicans 
come  across  the  border  as  seasonal  labor  and  their  heavy  influx  has 
created  the  problem  of  the  so-called  "wetbacks."  On  the  Canadian  bor- 
der, especially  in  the  Detroit  area  where  social  conditions  on  both  sides 
of  the  border  are  similar,  the  problem  of  commuting  across  the  boundary 
is  of  insignificant  proportions.  French  mines  and  industries  located  in 
France,  but  along  the  Belgian  and  the  Saar  borders  have  attracted  labor 
from  across  the  border  (cf.  Fig.  5-1).  There  is  a  zone  close  to  the  border 
where  daily  commuters  live;  in  a  second,  slightly  overlapping  zone  we 
find  commuters  who  return  home  only  over  the  weekend;  a  third  zone, 
that  of  seasonal  migrants,  is  not  distinctive,  partly  because  of  their  small 
number  in  this  particular  area,  and  partly  because  their  habitation  can  not 
be  localized  so  distinctly.19  We  do  not  have  comparable  data  for  the 
French  side  of  the  border.  It  can  only  be  assumed  that  there  also  a  sub- 
zone  of  factories  and  mines  which  employ  daily  commuters  can  be  dis- 
tinguished from  another  wider,  but  overlapping  zone  with  weekly  com- 
muters. Similar  conditions  exist  on  other  boundaries. 


FRONTIERS  AND  MEANS  OF  COMMUNICATIONS 

Among  the  factors  emphasizing  the  dividing  function  of  the  boundary 
is,  in  many  cases,  a  country's  communications  system,  the  extension  of 
which  is  halted  by  the  boundary.  Railroads  often  have  their  terminals  at 
some  distance  from  the  boundary,  or  have  more  restricted  service  across 
it  than  in  the  interior.  Good  roads  may  deteriorate  near  the  boundary  into 
badly  maintained  secondary  roads  and  trails.  Even  internal  boundaries 
may  have  similar  effects.  The  eastern  Rhode  Island-Massachusetts  bound- 
ary was  superimposed  as  a  straight  line  on  an  area  which  had  already 
developed  irregular  road  and  subdivisional  patterns.  Though  roads  may 
not  be  affected  in  this  case,  services  such  as  gas,  electricity,  and  water 
end  abruptly  at  the  border.  School  districts  may  have  an  inconvenient 
shape.20 

There  are,  however,  frontiers  where  the  opposite  effect  occurs.  On 
heavily  fortified  boundaries,  military  roads,  built  for  heavy  loads,  form 
a  dense  net  close  to,  and  occasionally  lead  to,  the  very  boundary  where 

19  R.  Capot-Rey,  La  region  sarroise  (Nancy,  1934). 

20  E.  Ullman,  "The  Eastern  Rhode  Island-Massachusetts  Boundary  Zone,"  Geo- 
graphical Review,  Vol.  29  ( 1929),  pp.  41  ff. 


THE  IMPACT  OF  BOUNDARIES  119 

they  terminate.  Before  World  War  II  the  Italians  pursued  such  policy  on 
their  European  boundaries,  and  extensive  road-building  preceded  their 
attack  on  Ethiopia.21  Another  illustration  is  the  six  thousand-mile  trans- 
Siberian  railway  which  was  pushed  to  completion  in  1904,  mainly  for  the 
purpose  of  defense.  Military  considerations  also  account  for  other  railroad 
developments  in  Soviet  Asia  after  World  War  II.  Another  influence  of 
boundaries  can  be  observed  along  every  administrative  boundary.  People 
in  small  towns  or  on  dispersed  farms  have  business  to  transact  with  au- 
thorities, as  for  instance  the  tax  collector,  the  courts,  the  school  board,  or 
the  county  agent.  They  will  visit  the  seat  of  the  local  government  more  or 
less  regularly  and,  on  the  occasion  of  these  visits,  do  their  shopping.  The 
administrative  centers  therefore  attract  the  population  even  if  other  towns 
may  be  in  closer  proximity. 

THE  FRONTIER  AND  ITS  IMPACT  ON 
LOCATION  AND  INDUSTRIES 

Frontier  zones  are  to  a  certain  degree  at  a  disadvantage  as  far  as  their 
economic  activities  are  concerned.  A  new  boundary  is  a  strong  deterrent 
to  new  investments  and  may  even  cause  some  industries  to  migrate  farther 
inland.  However,  mines,  primary  agricultural  production,  industries  de- 
pendent upon  raw  material,  and  in  general  industries  whose  histories  and 
needs  are  closely  linked  with  their  geographical  location  cannot  easily 
move  away  from  boundaries.  Other  industries  are  less  intimately  wedded 
to  a  certain  location,  especially  defense  industries,  and  will  be  transferred 
to  safer  locations  inland,  especially  when  war  or  danger  of  war  moves  the 
frontier  too  close  for  comfort.  Well  known  is  the  example  of  the  Soviet 
Union,  where  whole  industries  have  been  moved  east  from  the  western 
frontier  zones  into  the  Volga  region,  behind  the  Urals,  and  into  Asia.  This 
movement  reached  its  climax  in  the  years  of  World  War  II.  It  seems  to 
have  slowed  down  considerably  since  then,  partly,  no  doubt,  because  the 
satellite  states  have  largely  taken  over  the  boundary  functions  of  the  west- 
ern provinces,  partly  also  because  of  the  difficulties  of  this  wholesale  mi- 
gration. In  the  United  States,  a  trend  can  be  observed  to  establish  new 
critical  defense  installations  far  inland,  in  the  Tennessee  valley,  in  the 
deserts  of  the  western  plateaus,  but  nowhere  near  the  borders  or  coasts, 
which  can  be  easily  reached  from  across  the  sea.  In  comparison,  Sweden, 

21  D.  Whittlesey,  "The  Impact  of  Effective  General  Authority  Upon  the  Landscape," 
Annals  of  the  Association  of  American  Geography,  Vol.  25  (1935),  pp.  85  ff,  has 
described  the  formation  of  defense  zones  or  shells. 


120  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

lacking  large  spaces  remote  from  boundaries  such  as  exist  in  the  United 
States,  has  effected  a  transfer  of  critical,  especially  aircraft,  industries  to 
underground  locations  offering  relative  safety  against  attacks  from  the  air. 
The  Swedish  example  emphasizes  the  limitations,  in  aerial  warfare,  of  a 
policy  bent  on  establishing  and  transferring  industrial  plants  inland  and 
far  from  coasts  and  borders,  since  these  locations  do  not  necessarily  deter 
an  aggressor  striking  from  the  skies. 


22 


CROSS-BOUNDARY  INFLUENCES 

Hardly  any  frontier  has  escaped  being  influenced  from  across  the 
boundary.  The  influence  may  be  only  a  few  words  of  the  foreign  language 
helping  to  shape  the  local  dialect,  or  a  few  borrowed  habits  in  custom  and 
food.  It  may  lead  to  a  more  or  less  pronounced  bilingualism,  to  likes  or 
more  often  dislikes  of  the  neighbor,  to  rare  or  frequent  intermarriages,  or 
at  least  to  knowing  more  than  one  way  of  life.  Frontier  people,  consciously 
or  not,  willingly  or  not,  absorb  some  of  the  ways  of  their  neighbor.23  Or 
they  retain  and  cling  to  older  customs  which  have  disappeared  elsewhere, 
developing  a  cultural  lag  in  areas  remote  from  centers  of  a  different  and 
often  more  rapid  cultural  growth.  The  gaucho  of  the  Argentinian  Pampa 
has  in  some  respects  customs  similar  to  those  of  his  neighbors  across  the 
frontier  in  Bolivia,  Paraguay,  or  Uruguay— customs  which  have  disap- 
peared from  the  vicinity  of  Buenos  Aires.  Sometimes  such  similarities 
across  a  frontier  are  remnants  of  former  political  alignments.  Nobody  will 
doubt  that  California  is  American  in  its  way  of  life  despite  the  Spanish- 
Mexican  atmosphere  suggested  by  some  missions,  churches,  or  place 
names.  But  few  people  realize  that  water  rights  in  California,  and  else- 
where in  the  southwest,  are  still  governed  by  law  derived  from  Roman 
law  in  its  Spanish-Mexican  tradition  and  not  by  the  Anglo-Saxon  common 
law.24 

CONTINUATION  OF  FEATURES  ORIGINATING  FROM 
BOUNDARIES  NO  LONGER  IN  EXISTENCE 

However  the  frontier  man  may  differ  from  his  co-national  in  the  interior, 
he  will  also  differ  from  the  people  across  the  boundary,  even  if  he  should 
belong  to  the  same  linguistic  or  other  minority  group.  This  is  due  to  his 

22  See  p.  189. 

23  Boggs,  op.  cit.,  p.  10,  speaks  in  this  connection  of  osmosis. 

24  Whittlesey,  "The  Impact  of  Effective  General  Authority  Upon  the  Landscape," 
loc.  cit.,  p.  54. 


THE  IMPACT  OF  BOUNDARIES  121 

necessary  adjustment  to  the  economy  and  administration  of  the  state  of 
which  he  is  a  citizen.  Economic  activity,  however,  shapes  the  cultural 
landscape  so  deeply  that,  should  such  an  international  boundary  cease  to 
exist,  many  former  features  tend  to  persist. 

One  such  feature  which  tends  to  persist  are  trade  areas.  In  theory,  a 
town  of  a  certain  size  will  dominate  a  more  or  less  circular  or  hexagonal 
trade  area.  Such  circular  areas  of  different  radii  overlap  according  to  size 
and  extent  of  services  offered  by  various  urban  areas.  Political  boundaries 
tend  to  distort  such  trade  areas  and  these  distortions  disappear  only  some 
time  after  the  disappearance  of  the  political  boundary.  This  is  true  also  of 
the  road  and  railroad  systems.  Although  roads  and  railroads  can  be  built 
quickly,  it  is  seldom  done  as  fast  as  is  technically  possible.  Certain  remind- 
ers of  an  old  boundary  may  survive  for  centuries.  The  street  plan  of  many 
German  cities  west  of  the  Rhine  and  south  of  the  Danube  is  still  deter- 
mined by  the  original  location  of  the  walls  and  main  streets  of  the  Roman 
castle  on  the  site  of  which  the  city  developed,  while  north  and  east  of  the 
ancient  Roman  boundary  other  patterns  prevail. 

Also  psychological  factors  may  be  very  persistent.  The  open,  optimistic, 
neighborly  ways  of  the  American  West  are  an  inheritance  of  frontier  days, 
where  life  would  have  been  impossible  without  the  unorganized  but  very 
efficient  help  of  the  neighbors.  On  the  other  hand,  the  aggressive  nation- 
alism of  the  French  of  Lorraine  reflects  a  frontier  mentality  of  an  alto- 
gether different  kind  in  this  much-fought-over  country. 

In  regions  which  have  been  fought  over  through  long  periods  we  often 
find  that  the  contest  has  been  instrumental  in  forcing  certain  characteris- 
tics upon  the  frontier  population  which  distinguish  them,  in  spite  of  their 
linguistic  and  religious  bonds,  from  their  neighbors.25  The  Saar  is  an  illus- 
tration of  a  frontier  area  whose  population  has  been  wooed  by  French  and 
Germans.  As  elsewhere  under  similar  conditions,  we  find  here  nationality 
traits  reflecting  consciousness  of  a  frontier  situation  which  is  precarious 
and,  at  the  same  time,  offers  opportunities  for  bargaining  on  a  political 
and  economic  plane.26 

IMPRINT  OF  THE  BOUNDARY  UPON  THE  LANDSCAPE 

A  boundary  becomes  more  ingrained  in  the  landscape  and  in  the  ways 
of  the  people  the  longer  it  exists.  This,  and  not  special  topographic  fea- 

25  Ibid. 

26  C.  C.  Held,  "The  New  Saarland,"  Geographical  Review,  Vol.  41  (1951),  esp. 
pp.  603  ff. 


122  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

tures,  is  the  main  reason  why  old  established  boundaries  seem  often  so 
much  better  than  newly  established  ones.  It  has  been  asserted  that  if 
boundaries  retain  their  locations  through  centuries,  or  reassume  them 
when  displaced,  this  is  in  itself  a  proof  of  the  peculiar  fitness  of  their 
location.  That  may  be  true  in  a  few  instances.  Usually,  however,  it  is  the 
very  existence  of  the  boundary  which  shapes  the  human  landscape  and 
makes  it  advisable  to  retain  old  boundary  sites  or  to  readopt  them.  This 
is  also  the  factual  background  for  the  argument  for  "historical"  bound- 
aries, specious  in  some  cases,  but  very  real  in  others.  On  the  other  hand, 
a  new  boundary,  however  artificial,  acquires  separating  features  of  its 
own  by  prolonged  existence.27  Boundary-makers,  especially  those  of  the 
Versailles  and  St.  Germain,  Trianon  and  Neuilly  treaties  of  1919,  have 
often  been  accused  of  geographical  ignorance,  of  imperialistic  greed,  or 
of  callous  disregard  of  the  popular  wishes.  Some  of  these  accusations  may 
be  well  founded.  However,  it  should  not  be  overlooked  that  every  new 
boundary  cuts  through  some  older  unit,  requires  adjustments,  and  will 
thereby  cause  a  painful  transition  for  some  groups.  In  areas  of  old  bound- 
aries such  birth  pains  are  forgotten;  they  may  even  never  have  been  felt 
painfully  because  boundaries  had  so  few  functions  in  former  centuries. 
The  human,  if  not  the  physical  landscape  has  changed  since  the  boundary 
was  established.  If  there  are  valid  reasons  for  a  boundary  change  there  is 
no  way  out  of  the  dilemma;  both  the  retention  of  the  old  or  the  creation 
of  a  new  boundary  will  hurt. 

THE  PRESTIGE  FACTOR 

These  factors  of  human  geography,  developed  over  a  lengthy  period, 
are  a  force  working  for  preservation  of  an  existing  boundary.  This  force 
may  in  some  cases  be  only  one  of  several  factors  and  in  itself  not  very 
strong;  it  is,  however,  closely  connected  with  nongeographical  conditions, 
such  as  questions  of  prestige.  Prestige  has  often  hindered  agreement  by 
nations  on  boundary  changes,  even  if  they  did  not  inconvenience  the  one 
partner  and  brought  obvious  advantages  to  the  other.  Only  where  the 
factor  of  prestige  does  not  enter  into  the  picture  are  such  arrangements 
possible.  It  was  possible  in  1927  for  Belgium  to  give  up  an  area  of  480 
square  miles  of  the  Congo  in  return  for  a  cession  by  Portugal  of  ( Fig.  5-2 ) 
little  more  than  one  square  mile  near  Matadi  in  the  estuary  of  the 
Congo  28— an  area  of  uncrystallized  boundaries.  But  it  seems  impossible 

27  G.  Weigand,  "Effects  of  Boundary  Changes  in  the  South  Tyrol,"  Geographical 
Review,  Vol.  40  ( July,  1950 ) . 

28  The  Statesman's  Yearbook,  1953,  p.  807. 


THE  IMPACT  OF  BOUNDARIES 


123 


OCEAN 

DILOLO.BOOT 

111^'''  j:l::::EiiaabcthviUi 

I 

^..-_..^jj|  NORTHERN  |j  RHODESIA  j 
20  jjiiii  I&&] 

Fig.  5-2.  The  Congo  Territory:  Exchanges  Between  Belgium  and  Portugal. 


for  Austria  to  give  up  the  almost-exclave  of  Jungbluth,  containing  a  ham- 
let in  mountainous  terrain.29  Other  exchanges  in  colonial  regions  have 
been  effected,  hardly  noticed  in  the  metropolitan  area  and  hardly  realized 
by  the  natives  of  the  area.  Once  a  territory  has  acquired  an  emotional 
value,  no  economic  quid  pro  quo  can  satisfy.  When  Switzerland  needed 
the  headwaters  of  a  tributary  of  the  Rhine,  the  Val  di  Lei,  for  a  power 
plant,  it  was  possible  to  reach  an  agreement  over  this  uninhabited  tiny 
area  concerning  use  and  indemnities,  but  not  concerning  the  transfer  of 
the  sovereignty  from  Italy  to  Switzerland.  If  boundaries  of  a  lower  order, 
that  is,  not  international  boundaries,  are  to  be  corrected,  however,  such 
rectification  is  no  longer  uncommon  though  by  no  means  easy. 


EMOTIONAL  ATTACHMENT 

It  is  difficult  to  distinguish  between  questions  of  prestige  and  true  emo- 
tional attachment  based  on  long  common  history,  memories,  or  symbolical 
values.  The  Italian  people  have  easily  forgotten  the  loss  of  Savoy,  which 
was  ceded  to  France  as  the  price  for  Napoleon  Ill's  help  in  bringing  about 
the  unification  of  Italy  in  the  war  with  Austria.  Savoy  was  the  home  of 
the  kings  of  Italy,  but  was  not  Italian  in  language  or  tradition.  In  most 
parts  of  Italy  the  identification  with  the  dynasty  was  never  strong.  The 

2  9  See  p.  63. 


124  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

simultaneous  cession  of  Nizza  was  resented  more  strongly,  but  still  did  not 
influence  Italian  politics  to  a  large  degree.  On  the  other  hand,  the  question 
of  Trieste  is  still  one  to  stir  up  widespread  emotions.  Trieste  is  only  partly 
Italian-speaking,  is  economically  ill-fitted  for  a  union  with  Italy,  and  has 
belonged  to  Italy  for  only  twenty-seven  years.  However,  it  had  long  been 
a  symbol  of  success  or  failure,  and  any  attack  on  its  status  evokes  feelings 
of  resentment. 

At  one  time  the  slogan  "Fifty-four  forty  or  fight"  could  bring  America 
to  the  brink  of  war.  It  is  forgotten.  Nothing  binds  the  overwhelming 
majority  of  Americans  to  the  once  claimed  territory.  If  there  exists  some 
antagonistic,  often  unreasoned  anti-British  feeling,  it  has  other  sources. 
The  Revolutionary  War  and  the  colonial  period  is  still  fought  over  in  the 
schools  and  remembered  at  Fourth  of  July  celebrations.  In  the  east  it  left 
a  few  tangible  monuments.  Many  Americans  pride  themselves  on  being 
descendants  from  the  fighters  of  this  time.  Yet  no  boundary  questions  are 
involved.  In  contrast,  in  Europe,  and  occasionally  in  other  continents,  such 
historical  memories  are  usually  somehow  connected  with  boundary  prob- 
lems. This  makes  boundary  changes,  except  by  war,  extremely  difficult. 

COASTAL  BOUNDARIES 

Despite  all  these  forces  working  for  the  status  quo  there  are,  on  almost 
every  boundary,  also  forces  which  work  for  change.  Stability,  stronger  or 
weaker  pressure,  and  actual  change  result  from  the  interaction  of  all  these 
forces.  There  is  hardly  any  boundary  the  stability  of  which  is  absolute. 
Problems  exist  even  at  boundaries  such  as  coasts  which  by  their  very 
physical  nature  seem  destined  for  stability.  We  have  referred  briefly  to 
the  proclamation  by  the  United  States  that  it  would  regard  the  continental 
shelf  as  pertaining  to  the  United  States.30  We  have  mentioned  in  the  same 
place  that  other  states  took  this  as  an  occasion  to  expand  their  claims 
seaward.  In  one  case,  that  of  Australia,  the  motive  is  to  keep  the  Japanese 
fishermen  away,  a  very  understandable  desire  in  view  of  the  events  of  the 
last  war,  but  a  one-sided  act  subject  to  challenge  at  some  future  moment. 
The  issue  of  the  ownership  of  the  submerged  lands  was  settled,  at  least 
temporarily,  by  act  of  Congress  of  May  22,  1953.  This  act  gives  owner- 
ship to  the  coastal  states  within  a  zone  of  three  miles  between  the  low- 
water  mark  and  the  outer  limit  of  the  coastal  waters,  and  ten  and  a  half 
miles  along  the  coasts  of  Florida  and  Texas  ( Fig.  5-3 ) .  It  does  not  apply 
to  tidal  land— the  zone  lying  between  mean  high  and  mean  low  water 

30  See  p.  101. 


THE  IMPACT  OF  BOUNDARIES 


125 


TEXAS 


MEXICO 

J.R.F. 


Fig.  5-3.  State  Boundaries  in  the  Continental  Shelf:  Louisiana  (3  miles),  Texas  (10^ 
miles):  (1)  High  Seas  of  Gulf  of  Mexico;  (2)  Continental  Shelf;  (3)  Salt  Dome 
Oilfields. 

which  is  submerged  only  temporarily  generally  twice  a  day.  Fishing  rights 
have  played  a  considerable  role  in  the  development  of  the  concept  of 
territorial  waters.  France  has  retained  two  tiny  islands  off  the  coast  of 
Newfoundland— Saint  Pierre  and  Miquelon— as  bases  for  its  fishing  fleet, 
and  until  1904  clung  to  the  right,  acquired  by  the  Treaty  of  Utrecht  in 
1713,  for  its  fishermen  to  land  on  the  coast  and  dry  their  catch  within 
definite  periods.  France  still  retains  fishing  rights  within  the  territorial 
waters.  Similarly,  American  rights,  cause  of  many  recriminations,  were 
fixed— and  curtailed— only  in  1910.  Fishing  rights  in  territorial  waters  and 
conflicts  arising  therefrom  have  also  contributed  to  acerbate  the  relations 
between  Japan  and  Russia. 

One  would  hardly  expect  the  coast  circling  the  Arctic  Ocean  to  be  the 
stage  for  similar  problems.  Actually,  nowhere  else  have  coastal  powers 
extended  their  claims  so  far  seaward  as  here.  Starting  in  1927,  the  Soviet 
Union  proclaimed  the  sector  principle,  claiming  sovereignty  over  all  the 
sea,  including  undiscovered  islands,  in  a  sector  with  its  base  on  the  coast 
extending  from  Murmansk  to  the  Chukchee  Peninsula  and  having  its 
apex  at  the  North  Pole.  The  United  States  government  has  never  recog- 
nized the  validity  of  this  legal  construction,  although  all  other  powers 


126 


THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 


Fig.  5-4.  The  Sector  Principle  in  the  Arctic  Ocean. 

having  interests  in  the  Arctic  or  Antarctic  have  recognized  it 31  (Fig.  5-4). 
Coasts  are  not  only  a  basis  for  expansion,  they  are  also  open  to  all  kinds 
of  intrusion.  It  has  been  said  that  coastal  peoples  have  a  wider  horizon, 
are  more  influenced  by  foreign  thought  than  people  inland,  not  excluding 
those  on  land  boundaries.  There  is  a  difference,  however,  between  differ- 
ent types  of  coasts.  Steep,  rocky  coasts;  straight,  sand-dune  girded  coasts 
on  shallow  waters  and  mangrove-grown  tropical  coasts  may  be  practically 
inaccessible.  High  mountains  a  short  distance  behind  the  coast  may  re- 
strict the  influences  coming  from  overseas.  They  may  also  force  the  coastal 
population  to  look  for  their  livelihood  on  the  water.  Phoenicia  and  Greece 
are  the  classical  examples;  Norway,  Iceland,  and  to  a  certain  degree 
Japan,  the  modern  ones.  However,  not  every  population  takes  to  the  sea. 
Neither  the  Indians  of  California  nor  the  Araucanian  Indians  of  Chile 


31  See  pp.  82-84. 


THE  IMPACT  OF  BOUNDARIES  127 

ever  became  seafaring,  though  confined  by  mountains  and  sea  to  an  in- 
hospitable narrow  strip  of  land. 

All  these  Pacific  Indians  remained  culturally  secluded  because  they 
never  were  able  to  reach  an  opposite  coast.32  Phoenicians  and  Greeks 
brought  home  cultural  achievements  from  many  coasts.  There  is  no  doubt 
that  any  accessible  coast  is  open  to  varied  influences,  while  land  borders 
are  open  only  to  influences  from  one  neighbor. 

The  negative  factor  in  such  accessibility  is  that  coasts  are  open  also  to 
military  invasions.  Great  Britain  has  been  invaded  by  Celts,  Romans, 
Anglo-Saxons,  Danes,  Norsemen,  and  French  with  results  still  to  be  found 
in  the  British  demographic,  linguistic,  and  cultural  heritage.  With  the 
great  outburst  of  European  activity  in  the  period  of  the  Renaissance  and 
overseas  explorations,  Europeans  invaded  the  coasts  of  all  other  conti- 
nents. Following  invasion,  the  course  of  development  depended  on  physi- 
ographic factors  in  the  other  continents,  political  and  demographic  condi- 
tions in  the  European  homelands,  and  cultural  levels  of  the  non-European 
countries.  Escarpments  and  rapids  in  rivers  kept  the  European  explorers 
on  the  coasts  of  Africa,  whereas  the  accessible  St.  Lawrence  and  Missis- 
sippi led  the  French  rapidly  into  the  interior  of  America.  A  low  level  of 
civilization  of  the  indigenous  population  kept  the  Europeans  between 
mountains  and  sea  in  eastern  Australia,  while  the  advanced  civilization  of 
Peru  and  Mexico  lured  the  Spaniards  across  tremendous  mountain  bar- 
riers. Few  Frenchmen  were  available  for  the  penetration  of  North 
America,  while  the  coastal  string  of  British  colonies  soon  became  the  basis 
for  westward  migration  on  a  broad  front.  In  the  highly  civilized  Asian 
countries,  colonies  along  the  coasts  remained  either  purely  commercial 
bases— Hongkong  and  Macao  are  relics  on  the  coast  of  China— or  became 
bases  for  political  domination  but  not  mass  immigration.  In  India,  Indo- 
nesia, the  Philippines,  and  Burma  this  process  has  run  its  full  course; 
political  domination  has  vanished,  but  not  without  leaving  a  deep  cultural 
imprint. 

An  interesting  example  of  a  country  with  coastal  boundary  is  offered  by 
Palestine.  Invasions  from  all  directions  have  penetrated  into  this  country. 
Invasions  from  north  and  south  usually  passed  through,  using  this  poor 
and  small  country  as  a  corridor  between  sea  and  desert  to  more  alluring 
goals  in  the  great  river  valleys.  To  the  nomads  from  the  east,  however- 
warlike  but  small  tribes— it  appeared  a  "country  flowing  with  milk  and 
honey."  From  Abraham  to  the  Arabs  these  intruders  settled  there.  Less 

32  German  geographers  have  a  special  term,  Gegenkiiste,  which  recently  has  found 
entry  into  English-language  geographical  writing. 


128  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

successful  have  been  the  intruders  from  the  sea,  Philistines  as  well  as 
Crusaders.  Their  latest  successors  are  the  Jews,  whose  state  in  its  con- 
figuration resembles  that  of  its  historic  predecessors  with  its  domination 
of  the  coastal  plain  and  odd-shaped  extensions  inland. 

As  mentioned  before,  the  successful  resurrection  of  long-abolished 
boundaries  has  been  regarded  as  proof  of  their  location  in  a  geographi- 
cally favorable  location.  Such  a  statement  can  not  be  maintained  as  a 
general  rule.  The  example  of  Palestine  (cf.  Fig.  7-7,  p.  192)  demonstrates 
its  fallacies  especially  clearly,  but  also  shows  the  extent  of  its  validity. 
The  eastern  boundary  of  Palestine  has  been  the  edge  of  the  desert  time 
and  again.  However,  this  desert  boundary  shows  a  continuous  change,  de- 
pending upon  the  mutual  strength  of  nomads  and  settlers,  as  well  as  upon 
the  changes  of  climatic  conditions,  expressed  in  a  series  of  moist  or  dry 
years.  In  western  Palestine  invaders  from  the  sea  could  penetrate  the 
plains,  while  the  natives,  pushed  into  a  defensive  position,  held  on  to  the 
high  plateaus.  Saul  and  David  held  the  Judean  plateau  against  the  Philis- 
tines; but  at  the  same  period  the  Jebusites  still  maintained  their  stronghold 
on  the  least  accessible  part  of  the  plateau,  Jerusalem  and  Mount  Zion. 

BOUNDARIES  AND  POPULATION  PRESSURE 

It  would  be  strange  if  ancient  boundaries,  even  those  that  served  well 
in  the  past,  would  fit  equally  well  into  modern  conditions.  Hardly  any  of 
the  human  conditions  have  remained  unchanged.  Almost  everywhere, 
population,  its  increase  and  its  pressure,  has  undergone  basic  changes. 
Again  Palestine— indeed,  all  the  countries  of  the  Fertile  Crescent— offers 
a  good  example.  In  the  steppe  and  desert,  living  room  is  sparse.  Nomadic 
tribes  have  to  migrate  as  soon  as  their  herds  have  eaten  all  edible  food  in 
one  locality.  They  can  return  to  the  same  place  only  after  the  pasturage 
has  had  a  long  period  of  recovery.  They  need,  therefore,  much  space.  If 
the  tribe  increases,  it  has  to  increase  its  herds  or  starve.  Increased  herds 
need  more  pasture.  Soon  the  size  limit  is  reached  and  quarrels  with  other 
tribes  over  pasture  follow.  Each  tribal  group  alone  is  small  and  not  able 
to  conquer  the  fertile  land  of  the  settlers.  This  land  lures  them,  however, 
and  finally  many  tribes  unite  to  conquer  the  settled  land,  originally  to 
convert  it  into  pasture,  usually  ending  by  becoming  sedentary  themselves. 
Akkadians  and  Aramaeans,  Hebrews  and  Chaldaeans,  Elamites  and  Hyk- 
sos,  all  repeated  the  same  story.  Mohammed  united  the  Arabs  with  a  re- 
ligious idea  and  his  successors  led  the  Arabs  farther  afield  than  any  of  the 
preceding  waves  of  nomadic  conquerors  had  been  able  to  penetrate. 


THE  IMPACT  OF  BOUNDARIES 


129 


Fig.  5-5.  The  United  States-Mexican  Boundary. 

The  same  story  is  repeated  in  all  the  steppe  and  desert  countries  of  the 
world,  and  in  other  primitive  societies.  Overpopulated  Pacific  Islands 
sent  their  surplus  population  to  people  uninhabited  islands.  The  Maoris 
reached  New  Zealand  only  a  short  time  ahead  of  the  white  man. 

Under  conditions  of  technological  progress  countries  can  occasionally 
absorb  part  or  all  of  a  population  increase.  England  at  the  time  of  the  in- 
dustrial revolution  is  the  classic  example.  But  the  Greeks,  in  the  period 
of  their  largest  cultural  progress,  sent  out  scores  of  colonies.  The  early 
medieval  German  tribes,  at  the  time  when  they  were  adopting  the  more 
productive  three-field  agricultural  rotation,  and  had  started  using  the  iron 
ax  for  clearing  the  forest,  were  pushing  into  the  sparsely  settled  Slavic 
countries  to  the  east. 

Population  pressure  is  still  one  of  the  most  powerful  forces  causing  emi- 
gration, immigration,  and  conquest  to  win  "Lebensraum."  This  urge  to 
obtain  new  living  space  can  be  abused  dishonestly,  as  it  was  by  Hitler  and 
Mussolini  who,  at  the  same  time  clamored  for  new  space  for  their  popula- 
tion surplus  and  initiated  a  program  for  a  more  populous  nation  at  home. 
This  can  not  disguise  the  fact  that  population  pressure  is  a  real  problem. 
In  this  chapter  we  do  not  deal  with  the  question  of  whether  population 
pressure  can  be  relieved  by  other  measures  than  boundary  changes;  here 
it  must  suffice  to  point  out  that  population  pressure  still  accounts  in  our 
time  for  major  boundary  problems. 

An  American  problem  is  that  of  the  "wetbacks"  on  the  southern  bound- 
ary between  the  United  States  and  Mexico  33  (Fig.  5-5).  Mexico  with  its 

34  See  p.  377. 


130  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

rapidly  growing  population,  especially  among  the  poorest  groups  and  in 
the  poor  provinces  of  the  arid  northern  part  of  the  country,  can  not  pos- 
sibly absorb  all  its  people.  In  the  American  states  north  of  the  border  is  a 
large  labor  market  for  unskilled,  seasonal  labor.  The  result  is  a  heavy  pres- 
sure of  would-be  immigrants  from  the  relatively  overpopulated  Mexican 
area.  The  boundary  problem  is  a  social,  administrative,  and  local  problem 
at  present,  because  the  Mexican  government  has  not  espoused  the  cause 
of  the  "wetbacks"  so  far.  But  the  boundary  has  to  be  guarded  heavily,  its 
maintenance  is  costly,  and  still  it  remains  a  problem.  We  may  compare 
with  this  situation  the  population  pressure  of  Puerto  Rico.34  A  poor, 
poorly  educated,  Spanish-speaking,  landless,  agricultural  proletariat  is 
attracted  by  New  York,  because  even  the  least  paying  jobs  in  the  great 
metropolis  appear  as  a  great  improvement  compared  with  the  living  con- 
ditions at  home.  There  is  no  international  boundary  to  hinder  or  make 
difficult  migration  or  to  threaten  international  complications.  That  does 
not  eliminate  the  problem.  It  pushes  the  boundary  problem,  that  of  an 
administrative  boundary,  into  the  background,  and  emphasizes  the  prob- 
lem of  social  and  racial  discrimination  and  adjustment. 

BOUNDARIES  AS  SOCIAL  DIVIDES 

Even  social  boundaries  may  be  mapped.  Occasionally  a  street  is  a  very 
distinct  boundary  between  a  "restricted"  area  and  one  peopled  by  a  racial 
minority.  However,  such  boundaries  have  less  staying  power  than  inter- 
national ones. 

Under  the  racial  policy  of  the  Union  of  South  Africa  the  native  Bantus 
are  theoretically  confined  to  reservations  which  have  insufficient  resources. 
The  Bantus  are  forced  to  migrate  into  the  mines  and  compounds  of  the 
South  African  gold  fields  or,  less  often,  to  farms  to  find  their  living. 
In  order  to  maintain  the  artificial  social  order  the  Union  is  forced  to 
strengthen  its  segregation  policy.  Enclaves  or  neighboring  areas  which  do 
not  conform  to  the  South  African  pattern  are  an  actual  or  potential  threat 
to  the  social  order  of  the  Union.  This  has  already  led  to  the  practical 
annexation  of  South-West  Africa,  despite  the  protest  of  the  United  Na- 
tions. There  is  also  a  mounting  pressure  for  incorporation  of  the  British 
protectorate  in  Basutoland,  Swaziland,  and  Bechuanaland  (cf.  Fig.  3-2, 
p.  60),  and  for  expanding  the  Union  to  the  Rhodesias. 

Social  boundaries  of  the  kind  existing  in  the  United  States  can,  politi- 
cally and  sociologically,  be  highly  disturbing,  and  the  social  boundaries 

33  See  p.  377. 


THE  IMPACT  OF  BOUNDARIES  131 

in  South  Africa  which  are  the  expression  of  the  Apartheid  principle  may 
contribute  at  some  future  date  to  explosive  developments  affecting  African 
lands  far  beyond  the  boundaries  of  South  Africa.  Population  pressure, 
more  than  ever  before,  affects  boundary  structures  seriously.  It  was  popu- 
lation pressure,  combined  with  an  open-door  policy  of  the  British  colonial 
administration,  which  led  to  mass  immigration  of  Indians  into  Burma, 
Ceylon,  and  the  Malayan  Peninsula;  into  the  latter  Chinese  came  in  even 
greater  numbers  (cf.  Fig.  10-3,  p.  378).  World  War  II  and  its  aftermath 
has  stopped  this  migration,  and  forced  many  Indians,  especially  from 
Burma,  to  flee  their  new  home.  India  and  Ceylon  are  in  negotiation  about 
the  repatriation  of  a  large  part  of  the  Indians.  But  in  Malaya  the  creation 
of  a  plural  society  can  no  longer  be  undone.35 

STABILITY  OF  BOUNDARIES  OF  SPARSELY-POPULATED  AREAS 

We  can  not  neglect  the  fact  that  boundaries  between  areas  of  rapidly 
increasing  population  and  areas  of  sparse  population  are  threatened  in 
their  stability.  A  case  in  point  is  the  relationship  of  Australia  to  the  over- 
populated  lands  of  Southeast  Asia  and  of  Japan.  We  may  agree  with  Grif- 
fith Taylor's  assertion  that  "the  empty  lands"  of  Australia  are  a  burden  to 
the  Commonwealth  rather  than  an  asset,  and  their  vast  potentialities  exist 
only  in  the  mind  of  the  ignorant  booster.36  Although  he  estimates  that 
Australia  could,  mainly  in  the  southeast,  sustain  twenty  million  people 
under  the  present  standard  of  living,  he  admits  that  with  the  lower  stand- 
ards of  Central  Europe  this  number  could  be  doubled  and  trebled.  At 
present  only  seven  million  are  living  there.  Thus  it  may  still,  for  a  long 
time,  appear  an  empty  continent  to  the  overcrowded  Asian  nations.37 

The  villages  of  France  have  been  depopulated  by  the  combined 
effects  of  low  birth  rates  and  migration  to  the  cities.  Gradually  Italian 
and  Spanish  immigrants  are  taking  the  place  of  the  Frenchmen  who 
are  moving  into  the  cities.  As  long  as  the  cultural  attraction  of  France 
is  strong  enough  to  absorb  these  humble  immigrants,  this  process  is 
healthy  and  is  not  likely  to  cause  friction.  However,  should  France  no 
longer  be  able  to  assimilate  the  immigrants,  and  large  Italian  and  Spanish- 
speaking  areas  develop  on  the  French  side  of  the  boundary,  the  boundary 

35  J.  Morrison,  "Aspects  of  the  Racial  Problem  in  Malaya,"  Pacific  Affairs,  Vol.  22 
( December,  1949 ) .  The  official  census  of  1947  showed  that  the  Federation  of  Malaya 
had  a  population  of  4,908,000.  Of  this  total  the  Malays  made  up  49.5  per  cent,  the 
Chinese  38.4  per  cent,  and  the  Indians  10.8  per  cent;  see  also  pp.  379,  380, 

36  G.  Taylor,  Australia,  6th  ed.  (London,  1951),  p.  477. 

37  On  immigration  to  Australia,  see  p.  375, 


132  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

will  become  less  secure  despite  its  location  along  the  high  ranges  of  Alps 
and  Pyrenees. 


ECONOMIC  REASONS  FOR  BOUNDARY  OBSOLESCENCE 

Population  is  not  the  only  factor  for  change.  Significant  changes  which 
affect  the  economic  structure  of  a  country  are  likely  to  affect  its  boundary 
structure  as  well.  The  development  of  commercial  cities  and  later  of  a 
capitalistic  economy  has  been  responsible  to  a  large  degree  for  the  obso- 
lescence of  the  ill-defined  boundaries  between  small  feudal  principalities. 
This  process  has  been  going  on  since  the  Renaissance,  when  in  Italy  a  few 
powerful  cities,  republics,  or  city  states,  some  ruled  by  military  dictators 
called  condottieri— Venice  and  Florence,  as  well  as  Milan  or  Ferrara— 
established  viable  territorial  states  reaching  beyond  their  city  limits.  This 
happened  in  France  at  approximately  the  same  period,  when  autocratic 
kings  deprived  the  nobility  of  their  actual  rule  and  left  them  only  titles 
and  income,  but  no  power.  The  unification  of  France  in  administrative 
respects  was  not  complete  as  long  as  the  kings  retained  the  feudal  system 
of  levying  tolls  on  many  stations  along  the  main  trade  routes.  The  French 
Revolution  opened  the  way  for  the  transformation  of  the  artisan  and  mer- 
chant citizenry  into  a  capitalistic  society  by  sweeping  away  also  these 
internal  boundary-like  obstructions  together  with  other  obsolescent  insti- 
tutions. A  continuous  boundary  around  France  was  established,  indicating 
not  only  a  common  political  allegiance  but  also  economic  uniformity. 

This  process  has  not  yet  come  to  an  end.  Economic  and  technological 
development  has  made  the  economic  position  of  the  small  and  weak  coun- 
tries rather  precarious.  Immediately  after  World  War  II,  three  small 
countries,  Belgium,  the  Netherlands,  and  Luxembourg,  agreed  to  enter 
into  an  economic  Union,  Benelux.38  Although  the  implementation  of  the 
Union  is  proceeding  at  a  much  slower  pace  than  was  anticipated,39  it  has 
become  a  reality.  Larger  unions  of  the  European  countries  have  proceeded 
even  more  slowly,  especially  if  seen  with  the  impatient  eyes  of  many  Ameri- 
cans who  recognize  the  advantages  of  such  international  groupings  on  an 
economic  plane  but  are  too  distant  to  appreciate  the  numerous  intangible 

38  The  agreement  was  entered  into  in  September,  1944,  became  effective  in  October, 
1947,  and  the  common  customs  tariff  was  activated  on  January  1,  1948. 

39  Among  the  retarding  factors  the  following  are  worth  mentioning:  (a)  Belgium's 
situation  after  World  War  II  was  much  better  than  that  of  the  Netherlands,  which 
had  to  overcome  the  loss  of  its  colonial  empire  and  had  to  repair  the  severe  damage 
caused  by  the  opening  of  the  dykes  by  the  Germans  during  the  war;  ( b )  Belgium, 
Luxembourg,  and  the  Netherlands  were  in  many  ways  competitive  economic  systems; 
(c)  the  mentality  of  the  Belgian  and  Dutch  nations  differs  in  many  ways  of  life. 


THE  IMPACT  OF  BOUNDARIES 


133 


luNITED  0ENttA,B|C 

'I  f^  \  M  UNIOI^F  SOVIET  SOCIAIIST  REPUBLICS 

/f\:  Poland!:  ' 

■)**■•<  west  foctf  :■);.. .  ; .  ■ 
FRANCE         .A-v  _/         %-:'s.iS<* 

,"swiTri^L.AU5TOA  /.-"r-'.-y.  .-.vt 

^~/    HUNGARK  >T  '•  ■ 

•-'<i>i      RUMANIA 

■v.:::::::::;X:: 

VVWXJSUVtA\*t^^:-^: 

/BULGARIA' 

ALBANIA^       ^ (■-  ^—^  ' 

Fig.  5-6.  The  Satellite  Countries  of  Eastern  Europe. 


factors  which  the  unifying  process  has  to  overcome.  Another  important 
development  in  Western  Europe  was  the  conclusion  of  the  European  Coal 
and  Steel  Community  40  preceded  by  the  Organization  for  European  Eco- 
nomic Co-operation  ( 1947 ) ,  and  the  European  Payments  Union  ( 1950 ) . 


OBSOLESCENCE  OF  BOUNDARIES  IN  THE  SOVIET  ORBIT 

From  an  altogether  different  political,  social,  and  ideological  point  of 
view,  the  Communist  regime  in  the  Kremlin  has  embarked  on  an  integra- 
tion program  aimed  at  drawing  closer  to  the  Russian  center  the  satellite 
countries  of  Eastern  Europe  (Bulgaria,  Albania,  Rumania,  Hungary, 
Czechoslovakia,  Poland,  and  East  Germany  [Fig.  5-6]).  Under  this  pro- 
gram, the  requirements  of  the  U.S.S.R.  were  to  dictate  the  food  produc- 
tion and  the  industrial  output  (including  expansion  and  relocation  of 
industries)  within  these  countries.  This  long-range  policy  has  affected  in 
many  ways  the  boundary  system  within  the  Soviet  orbit.  Economically,  it 
has  expedited  the  withering-away  of  economic  boundaries  within  the 
Soviet  sphere  of  interest,  while  tightening  the  same  boundary  against  the 

40  The  Treaty,  proposed  by  French  Minister  for  Foreign  Affairs  Schuman,  was 
signed  on  April  18,  1951  and  instituted  on  August  10,  1952. 


134  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

West.  Politically,  the  Iron  Curtain  has  affected  both  external  and  internal 
boundaries;  for  the  same  Soviet  regulations  which  strangled  the  freedom 
of  movement  of  citizens  desiring  to  visit  countries  of  the  West  prevented 
them  from  traveling  freely  from  one  satellite  country  to  the  other.41 

OTHER  INSTANCES  OF  OBSOLESCENT  BOUNDARIES 

Outside  of  Europe  the  obsolescence  of  feudal  boundaries  has  led  to 
large-scale  territorial  reorganization,  particularly  in  India.  The  emergence 
of  the  new  international  boundary  between  India  and  Pakistan  should  not 
obscure  the  revolutionary,  yet  peaceful  disappearance  of  almost  all  of  the 
small  princely  states  and  of  thousands  of  miles  of  boundaries.  Such  bound- 
aries often  separated  areas  still  retaining  the  social  and  economic  condi- 
tions of  a  feudal  order— some  tiny,  some  quite  large— from  other  territories 
of  much  more  advanced  social  and  economic  development,  areas  standing 
at  the  threshold  of  modern  industrial  growth.  Although  the  political  im- 
portance of  these  boundaries  had  declined  under  British  overlordship, 
local  laws,  differing  systems  of  taxation,  and  occasionally  varying  condi- 
tions of  access  to  markets,  tended  to  increase  the  economic  differences  on 
the  two  sides  of  these  boundaries.  On  the  other  hand,  the  reorganization 
of  the  internal  political  geography  of  India  was  found  to  have  significant 
consequences  in  the  economic  field.  In  the  western  hemisphere,  the  at- 
tempts of  Argentina  to  eliminate  the  customs  boundaries  between  itself, 
Chile,  Bolivia,  and  Uruguay  point  to  analogous  developments. 

Differential  economic  growth  changes  the  value  and  the  functions  of 
boundaries  in  other  respects  also.  For  instance,  from  the  viewpoint  of 
Egypt,  it  has  at  times  been  possible  to  regard  the  boundary  between 
Egypt  and  the  Sudan  with  equanimity.  Modern  hydrological  develop- 
ments, such  as  the  construction  of  dams,  reservoirs,  and  flood  control 
projects,  have  made  the  Egyptians  more  and  more  aware  that  their  agri- 
culture depends  entirely  on  the  water  supply  systems  originating  in  the 
Sudan.  It  has  been  said  succinctly  that  Egypt  "lives  on  borrowed  water," 
and  it  is  for  this  reason  that  the  goal  of  Egypt's  policy  now  is  to  control 
the  Sudan,  preferably  by  eliminating  the  boundary  between  this  area  and 

Egypt- 
Interest  in  the  southern  and  southeastern  boundaries  of  what  is  now 

Saudi  Arabia  has  been  dormant  for  centuries  (cf.  Fig.  4-3).  Oman,  Ha- 

41  How  difficult  it  is  even  for  a  totalitarian  regime  such  as  the  Soviet  Union  to  keep 
an  Iron  Curtain  truly  intact  is  evidenced  by  the  fact  that  between  1950-54  not  less 
than  1,800,000  people,  or  10  per  cent  of  East  Germany's  population,  fled  to  West 
Germany!   (See  also  p.  362.) 


THE  IMPACT  OF  BOUNDARIES  135 

dhramaut,  and  the  smaller  sheikhdoms  were  looking  toward  the  Indian 
Ocean,  the  tribes  of  Inner  Arabia  were  concerned  with  the  west  and 
north.  The  wide  desert  between  them  was  of  little  concern  to  anyone. 
The  discovery  of  oil  has  changed  the  picture.  Saudi  Arabia  now  asserts  its 
sovereignty  over  the  "Empty  Quarter,"  in  order  to  be  able  to  lease  its 
suspected  hidden  oil  treasures  to  oil  companies. 

In  this  instance  modern  economic  developments  often  have  the  effect 
of  forcing  neighboring  countries  to  break  up  a  vaguely  delimited  border 
area  by  definite  boundary.  In  contrast,  established  boundary  lines  can 
become  an  obstacle  to  efficient  management  of  mines  under  modern  sub- 
surface exploitation  conditions  and  as  a  consequence,  new  boundary 
agreements  will  be  effected  between  two  adjacent  countries.  Occasionally 
in  such  instances,  the  new  subterranean  boundary  changes  agreed  upon 
will  deviate  from  the  surface  boundary.  This  was  the  arrangement  in  the 
salt  mines  of  Hall  and  Reichenhall  at  the  Austrian-German  boundary  and 
in  some  coal  mines  north  of  Maastricht  at  the  German-Dutch  boundary. 

Expansion  of  industry  leads  to  the  quest  for  new  markets,  new  sources 
of  raw  materials,  and  new  areas  of  capital  investment.  The  acquisition  of 
new  markets  and  new  sources  of  raw  materials  by  colonial  expansion  and 
imperialistic  conquest  has  been  responsible  for  the  disappearance  of  many 
boundaries.  The  independence  of  quite  a  few  states  has  been  undermined 
or  impaired  by  their  dependency  on  foreign  capital  for  development  of 
their  industrial  potential.  Thus  the  existence,  side  by  side,  of  states  on  a 
different  level  of  industrial  and  technological  development  has  led  in  some 
cases  to  conquest,  in  others  to  a  change  of  the  boundary  function. 

THEORIES  OF  ORGANIC  GROWTH  OF  STATES 

The  conditions  of  differential  population  growth,  population  pressure, 
differential  economic  and  technological  development  and  the  influence  of 
all  these  factors  upon  the  political  fate  of  countries  attracted  attention 
very  early,  and  led  to  the  organic  theory  of  the  state.  Friedrich  Ratzel 
developed  this  theory  and  applied  it  to  human  geography.42  He  was  the 
first  to  popularize  the  idea  that  "there  are  boundaries  which  change  so 
fast,  e.g.,  boundaries  of  expanding  peoples  that  it  is  possible  to  speak 
directly  of  migratory  boundaries.  .  .  .  The  apparently  rigid  boundary  is 
only  the  stoppage  of  a  movement."  43 

42  The  first  chapter  of  F.  Ratzel's  Politische  Geographie  (Miinchen  and  Berlin, 
1897),  is  called:  "Der  Staat  als  bodenstandiger  Organismus"  (The  State  as  Organism 
tied  to  the  Soil ) . 

43  Ibid.  (3rd  ed.  by  E.  Oberhummer),  p.  386. 


i36  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

Ellen  Churchill  Semple,  Ratzel's  best  known  American  disciple,  ex- 
pressed the  same  thought  in  the  sentence:  "As  territorial  expansion  is  the 
mark  of  growth,  so  the  sign  of  decline  is  the  relinquishment  of  land  that 
is  valuable  or  necessary  to  a  people's  well-being."  4i  She  exemplifies  this 
idea  among  other  examples  by  saying:  "Japan's  recent  aggression  (refer- 
ring to  the  Russian-Japanese  war  of  1904/05 )  against  the  Russians  in  the 
Far  East  was  actuated  by  the  realization  that  she  had  to  expand  into 
Korea  at  the  cost  of  Muscovite  ascendancy,  or  contract  later  at  the  cost 
of  her  own  independence."  45 

Ratzel  described  the  change  of  boundaries  in  the  spirit  of  the  scholarly 
observer.  So  did  Miss  Semple.  Some  of  Ratzel's  followers,  however,  tried 
to  use  such  geographical  observations  as  guide  for  political  action.  They 
could  refer  to  statements  of  the  master,46  quoted  here  in  the  translation 
by  Miss  Semple:  "The  struggle  for  existence  means  a  struggle  for 
space."  47  Thus  emerged  geopolitics.48  Its  leading  exponent,  Haushofer, 
has  incorporated  such  ideas  in  many  articles  and  in  his  book  on  bound- 
aries.49 He  writes:  "we  recognize  the  boundary  through  empirical  obser- 
vation as  an  organ,  a  living  being,  destined  either  to  shrink  or  to  push 
outward,  not  rigid,  in  no  case  a  line— in  contrast  to  the  theoretical  con- 
cept . . ." 

The  French  geographer  Ancel,  an  outspoken  foe  of  German  geopoli- 
tics 50  and  of  the  use  of  pseudogeographical  arguments  as  base  for  claims 
for  natural  boundaries,51  nevertheless  arrives  at  a  concept  which  does  not 
differ  basically  from  that  of  the  geopoliticians.  He  states  that  "a  boundary 
is  a  political  isobar  which  indicates  the  momentary  equilibrium  between 
two  pressures."  52  Like  those  he  means  to  criticize,  he  overstresses  the 
factors  working  for  change  and  neglects  those  working  for  stability.  He 
also  overlooks  the  fact  that  the  pressure  exerted  from  one  or  both  sides 
upon  a  boundary  may  not  result  in  a  dislocation  of  the  boundary,  but  in 
the  change  of  its  function.  As  important  as  such  a  change  of  function  may 

44  E.  C.  Semple,  Influence  of  Geographic  Environment  (New  York,  1911),  p.  163. 

45  Ibid.,  p.  66. 

46  F.  Ratzel,  Der  Lebensraum  (Tubingen,  1901),  p.  157.  Ratzel,  however,  was 
speaking  of  plants  and  animals  and  only  by  implication  of  man. 

47  Semple,  op.  cit.,  p.  170. 

48  General  problems  of  geopolitics  (versus  political  geography)  are  discussed  on 
pp.  5  ff .  Here  we  are  concerned  with  boundary  problems  as  seen  through  the 
glasses  of  geopolitics. 

49  K.  Haushofer,  Grenzen  ( Berlin-Grunewald,  K.  Vowinkel,  1927),  p.  13. 

50  J.  Ancel,  Geopolitique  (Paris,  1936). 

51  J.  Ancel,  Manuel  geographique  de  politique  Europeenne,  Vol.  I:  "L'Europe 
Centrale"  (Paris,  1936),  pp.  12  ff. 

52  J.  Ancel,  Geographie  des  frontieres  (Paris,  1938). 


THE  IMPACT  OF  BOUNDARIES  137 

be,  it  is  not  always  visible  on  a  map,  and  because  of  its  gradual  nature  is 
not  even  always  realized  immediately  by  the  frontier  people  themselves. 


IDEOLOGICAL  JUSTIFICATIONS  OF  EXPANSION 

Concepts  which  helped  the  conquering  white  man  to  forget  lingering 
pangs  of  his  conscience  have  found  their  expression  in  slogans  such  as 
"the  White  Man's  burden,"  or  "Manifest  Destiny."  53  Though  it  was  de- 
nounced later  as  hypocrisy,  at  one  time  hundreds  of  thousands  of  English- 
men honestly  believed  that  it  was  their  moral  duty,  burden  though  it  was, 
to  expand  the  boundaries  of  the  British  Empire  to  include  the  poor 
pagans,  to  educate  them  to  an  industrious  life,  and  to  administer  their 
lands  according  to  the  West's  advanced  concepts.54  In  1900,  a  great  ma- 
jority in  the  United  States  believed  in  their  divine  destiny  to  spread  Ameri- 
can civilization  westward.55 

The  communist  ideology,  also,  is  a  messianic  doctrine,  bent  on  "improv- 
ing" the  whole  world.  While  in  the  psychological  make-up  of  many  of  the 
Soviet  elite  the  lust  for  power  is  stronger  than  the  belief  in  their  aposto- 
late,  there  can  be  little  doubt  that  among  some  of  the  leaders  and  certainly 
within  the  ranks  of  communist  youth  a  deep  conviction  in  the  messianic 
destiny  of  communism  exists. 

There  are  probably  very  few  wars  of  conquest  in  which  the  ideological 
factor  is  absent.  Very  often,  as  in  the  Soviet  example,  it  can  not  be  sepa- 
rated from  other  motives.  Some  historians  and  political  scientists  are 
inclined  to  neglect  this  ideological  factor.  Marxian  philosophy  is  inclined 
to  stress  the  economic  causes  and  to  neglect  or  to  minimize  as  superstruc- 
ture, if  not  as  outright  fraud,  ideological  reasons.  In  some  cases  it  may  be 
impossible  to  come  to  an  agreement.  If  one  primitive  tribe  raids  another, 
it  may  be  impossible  to  refute  the  claim  that  the  underlying  cause  is  the 
opportunity  to  loot,  while  it  appears  that  the  tradition  of  the  nation  does 
not  accept  the  young  man  into  the  community  as  a  full-fledged  member 
before  he  has  proved  his  courage  and  valor  in  a  fight.  The  human  trait  of 
aggressiveness  has  been  investigated  thoroughly  in  respect  to  the  indi- 
vidual since  Freud  drew  attention  to  it  as  basic;  its  significance  as  motive 
power  in  international  relations  is  still  rather  obscure.  Fortunately,  it  is 
not  necessary  in  this  connection  to  prove  or  disprove  the  claim  that  certain 

53  See  pp.  10-12. 

54  D.  Whittlesey,  The  Earth  and  the  State  (New  York,  1944),  pp.  127-128. 

55  Although  a  popular  slogan  since  the  1840's,  "manifest  destiny"  was  clearly  en- 
dorsed by  a  majority  of  the  voters  as  late  as  the  presidential  elections  of  1900.  From 
then  on  it  lost  rather  quickly  its  unsophisticated  appeal;  see  also  pp.  10-12. 


138  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

ideological  motives  are  superstructures  according  to  Marx  and  his  follow- 
ers, or  sublimations  according  to  Freud  and  his  school,  or  primary  facts. 
Ideologies  are  subject  to  change.  The  feudal  economic  and  political 
order  was  possible  and  secure  only  as  long  as  undeveloped  transportation 
allowed  and  even  forced  every  small  area  to  lead  an  isolated  existence;  as 
long  as  social  stratification  was  regarded  as  willed  by  God;  and  as  long 
as  loyalty  was  regarded  as  a  purely  personal  bond.  The  feudal  order  dis- 
appeared long  ago,  but  remnants  have  existed  into  the  twentieth  century. 
Until  1918  the  Prince  of  Liechtenstein  was  sovereign  in  his  tiny  country, 
but  subject  to  the  Austrian  Empire  in  his  other  much  larger  estates.  Polish 
noblemen  were  simultaneously  subjects  of  the  Austrian  Emperor  and  the 
Russian  Czar.  Similar  conditions  survived  in  India  until  1947.  In  general, 
however,  the  territorial  state  replaced  the  feudal  state  all  over  the  world 
wherever  it  existed. 


TERRITORIAL  STATE  BOUNDARIES  AND  NATIONAL  STATES 

Our  concept  of  boundaries  is  essentially  still  that  of  the  territorial  state, 
inherited  from  the  concept  that  the  state  belongs  to  the  ruler.  Much  con- 
fusion has  been  created  in  our  minds  by  the  unrealized  fact  that  this 
concept  does  not  fit  present  conditions.  Men  regard  themselves  no  longer 
as  primarily  subjects  of  a  lord.  The  development  of  the  democratic  idea 
was  insolubly  connected  with  that  of  the  nation.  Men  are  emotionally 
bound  to  their  nation  and  feel  that  they  owe  allegiance  to  it.  The  national 
state  has  replaced  the  territorial  state  in  the  minds  of  men.  It  has  not  yet 
replaced  the  territorial  state  and  its  boundaries  on  the  surface  of  the 
earth.  Fortunate  is  the  country  where  state  and  nation  coincide  as  is  the 
case  in  the  United  States  and  in  most  American  republics.  In  Europe, 
however,  and  more  recently  in  Asia  and  Africa,  nation  is  more  and  more 
identified  with  a  common  language.56  Minorities  develop  a  double 
allegiance.  As  long  as  in  their  system  of  values  allegiance  to  the 
state,  to  the  people  with  whom  they  share  common  traditions,  takes  prece- 
dence over  allegiance  to  the  people  who  speak  the  same  language,  the 
inherited  framework  of  the  territorial  state  is  adequate.  Switzerland  in 
Europe  is  the  best  example  of  this  order  of  values.  The  overwhelming 
majority  of  Swiss  are  first  Swiss,  and  then  German,  French,  or  Italian.  As 
a  consequence  the  boundaries  of  Switzerland  have  not  changed  in  this 
age  of  nationalism. 

56  See  Chapter  11  on  the  Political  Geography  of  Languages. 


THE  IMPACT  OF  BOUNDARIES 


139 


GERMANY 


U.  S.  S.  R. 


Fig.  5-7.  The  Break-up  of  the  Hapsburg  Empire  after  1918. 

Another  outstanding  example  of  a  state  that  has  won  the  allegiance  of 
its  citizens  of  foreign  tongue  is  the  United  States.  Despite  individual  de- 
fections of  German-speaking  Americans  during  both  World  Wars,  and 
despite  the  widespread  suspicions  against  "hyphenated"  Americans  during 
World  War  I,  the  American  community  has  stood  the  test  of  time.  Actually 
most  immigrants  desire  for  themselves  or  at  least  for  their  children  to 
become  Americans  not  only  in  allegiance,  but  also  outwardly  by  adoption 
of  the  English  language  of  the  majority.  A  favorable  condition  is  also  that 
non-English  speaking  groups  do  not  as  a  rule  occupy  contiguous  terri- 
tories in  the  United  States. 

In  many  cases,  from  the  time  of  the  French  Revolution  to  the  most 
recent  claims  of  Franco  for  Gibraltar,  and  of  Afghanistan  for  the  Pushtu- 
speaking  areas,  the  linguistically  uniform  national  state  could  not  be  fitted 
into  borders  created  under  different  conditions.  Wars  and  revolutions  fol- 
lowed. Boundaries  were  changed,  either  by  unification,  as  in  Germany 
and  India,  or  by  breakup  of  large  states,  such  as  the  Hapsburg  (Fig.  5-7) 
and  the  Ottoman  Empires,  or  by  conquest  of  border  areas,  such  as  Alsace- 


140  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

Lorraine  or  Southern  Tyrol  and  Trieste,  to  name  only  a  few  better-known 
examples. 

Linguistic  boundaries  are  rarely  sharp.  Usually  a  zone  of  linguistically 
mixed  areas  exists.  Nor  do  language  boundaries  as  a  rule  follow  lines 
which  for  economic  or  other  reasons  would  be  more  convenient.  Hitler 
tried  to  solve  this  problem  by  two  devices;  first,  by  asserting  that  in  case 
of  irreconcilable  claims,  that  of  the  "higher  race,"  meaning  that  of  ethnic 
Germans,  had  to  prevail;  and  secondly,  by  transfer  of  populations.  In 
other  words,  the  stability  of  a  traditional  boundary  was  regarded  more 
important  than  other  factors. 

IDEOLOGICAL  GROUPINGS 

While  the  strife  for  national  boundaries  is  still  spreading  to  other  con- 
tinents, a  new  evaluation  of  boundaries  is  developing  as  a  concomitant  of 
a  changing  order  of  values.  For  an  increasing  number  of  people  allegiance 
to  some  political  ideology— democracy,  communism,  or  fascism— seems  to 
stand  first  in  their  order  of  values.  With  Hitler  and  Mussolini  this  striving 
to  unite  in  one  state  ideologically-uniform  people  was  not  reconciled  with 
traditional  national  values.  The  policy  of  the  two  dictators  was  a  mixture 
between  extreme  nationalism  and  the  attempt  to  regroup  nations  on  the 
basis  of  their  adherence  to  fascist  ideologies. 

Present-day  alignments  follow  not  only  ideological  groupings,  but  have 
tremendously  changed  the  function  of  boundaries.  Czechoslovakia's 
boundaries— with  two  small  exceptions— may  be  the  same  as  before  1939. 
However,  the  boundary  between  Czechoslovakia  and  Western  Germany 
has  become  a  part  of  the  Iron  Curtain  and  almost  all  traffic  has  stopped 
across  it.  Barbed  wire  barricades  on  all  roads  have  replaced  the  old  simple 
signs  announcing  the  existence  of  a  boundary.  On  the  other  side,  with  the 
progressing  integration  of  Czechoslovakia  into  the  Soviet  economic  bloc, 
the  boundaries  of  Czechoslovakia  with  the  U.S.S.R.,  Poland,  and  Hungary 
are  losing  some  of  their  functions.  We  have  mentioned  this  process  before 
in  its  economic  aspects  which  lead  to  the  creation  of  large  economic  units 
in  Eastern  as  well  as  in  Western  Europe.  With  the  creation  of  the  Soviet 
bloc  the  boundaries  lose  also  some  of  their  political  and  military  functions. 
Soviet  troops  may  not  actually  cross  the  boundary  into  Czechoslovakia; 
they  could  do  so  in  case  of  need  without  provoking  an  international  con- 
flict. 

Perhaps  even  more  significant,  education  on  both  sides  of  the  boundary 
is  organized  along  the  same  lines.  The  Russian  language  is  being  taught 


THE  IMPACT  OF  BOUNDARIES  141 

so  thoroughly  that  engineers  and  probably  other  professional  people  in 
the  future  should  have  no  difficulty  in  exerting  their  skill  in  other  countries 
of  the  Soviet  orbit  without  preparatory  adjustment.  The  legal  systems  are 
rapidly  shaped  after  a  uniform  pattern.  The  Russification  program  which 
at  present  sweeps  through  the  lands  of  the  Soviet  orbit  would,  if  con- 
tinued radically,  gradually  erase  the  cultural  distinctions  within  the  large 
family  of  nations  of  the  Soviet  Union  and  its  satellite  nations. 

In  the  tearing-down  of  cultural  boundaries  which  characterize  the 
Soviet  system,  the  religious  differences  that  were  factors  in  the  conflicts 
between  Roman-Catholic  Czechs  and  Poles  on  the  one  side,  Russians  and 
Ukrainians  on  the  other  side,  would,  according  to  Soviet  planning,  gradu- 
ally decrease  and  make  way  for  the  uniformity  of  materialistic-Marxian 
philosophy. 

This  development  in  the  communistic  ideological  orbit  is  not  matched 
in  the  democratic  world.  Here  the  trend  to  unification  has  found  its  ex- 
pression, as  pointed  out  before,  in  weakening  certain  boundary  functions 
in  the  economic  and  military-political  realms.  Here  the  ideological  factor 
has  played  a  subsidiary  role,  not  vigorous  enough  to  modify  strong  eco- 
nomic considerations.  In  the  United  States,  tariff  questions  and  immigra- 
tion restrictions  are  regarded  by  many  as  of  such  overriding  importance 
that  their  ideological  repercussions  are  hardly  taken  into  consideration. 
If,  nevertheless,  a  democratic  community  of  states  is  emerging,  it  is  mainly 
as  a  result  of  resistance  to  the  fascist  and  communist  pressures  of  the  last 
two  decades.  Such  a  state  lacks  the  cohesion  which  religious  communities 
have  achieved  occasionally  in  the  past. 

CONCLUSIONS 

We  arrive,  therefore,  at  the  conclusion  that  human  progress  and  natural 
changes  are  continuously  at  work  to  change  the  functions  of  boundaries 
and  their  value  for  the  bounded  areas.  Demographic,  economic,  and  ideo- 
logical developments  interact  in  this  process.  Nevertheless,  boundary 
changes  occur  only  at  intervals  and  usually  as  the  result  of  wars,  conquest, 
or  revolution.  There  are  strong  forces,  economic,  historical,  and  ideologi- 
cal, which  work  for  stability.  Stability  does  not  mean  absence  of  change; 
it  includes  change  of  function.  An  existing  boundary  may  not  only  acquire 
new  functions,  it  may  also  gradually  lose  functions  to  the  point,  if  not  of 
complete  vanishing,  of  being  reduced  to  the  performance  of  unspectacular 
functions,  as  in  the  case  of  internal  boundaries  which  do  not  give  cause 
for  armed  conflicts. 


CHAPTER 


6 


Political  Core  Areas, 
Capital  Cities,  Communications 


INTERIOR  ZONES  AS  "CORE"  AREAS 

Interior  areas  form  as  a  rule  the  main  body  of  a  political  unit.  Only  in 
small  political  units  of  elongated  form  do  we  find  territories  consisting 
mainly  of  frontier  zones.  Whereas  frontier  zones  play  a  definite  and  spe- 
cific role  in  the  political  geography  of  any  country,  interior  areas  differ 
widely  and  can  not  in  their  manifold  ramifications  be  discussed  as  units 
which  share  the  same  characteristics.  Large  parts  of  the  interior  are  of 
interest  to  the  political  geographer  only  insofar  as  they  add  bulk  to  the 
political  unit,  either  in  size  or  in  population,  in  raw  materials  or  in  finished 
products,  in  distance  or  in  diversity.  There  are,  however,  parts  of  a  politi- 
cal unit,  usually  parts  of  its  interior,  which  have  special  significance  for 
the  body  politic.  These  parts  are  called  core  areas. 

THE  CORE  AREA  IN  REGIONAL  AND  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

In  regional  geography  the  core  area  is  usually  considered  that  part  of 
a  region  in  which  the  characteristic  features  of  a  region  can  be  observed 
best  because  they  prevail  over  other  incidental  features.  Thus  the  core  of 
the  Middle  West  corn  belt  is  in  areas  where  other  types  of  agriculture  do 
not  play  a  significant  role  and  where  industry  also  is  dependent  on  or 
serves  largely  this  particular  form  of  agriculture.  Hog  raising,  slaughter- 
houses, and  farm  machinery  factories  are  characteristic  of  the  corn  belt. 

142 


CORE  AREAS,  CAPITAL  CITIES,  COMMUNICATIONS  143 

A  political  core  area  is  somewhat  different.  Within  its  often  relatively 
small  area  is  concentrated  the  political  power  of  a  state  or  of  a  secondary 
political  unit.1  What  happens  in  the  core  area  has  ramifications  far  beyond 
the  area  itself. 

THE  CAPITAL 

For  a  preliminary  identification  of  the  core  of  a  political  unit  it  is  gen- 
erally sufficient  to  identify  the  capital  city.2  The  capital  city  contains  the 
central  executive  organs  of  a  political  unit  and  commonly  other  central 
institutions,  judicial,  legislative,  educational,  and  cultural.  A  differentia- 
tion should  be  made  between  those  institutions  closely  connected  with 
the  function  of  a  capital  and  those  that  are  in  an  area  irrespective  of 
whether  the  capital  is  there.  On  the  other  hand,  these  latter  features  may 
provide  the  explanation  for  the  location  of  many  a  capital  in  a  specific 
area. 

RELATIONSHIP  OF  CORE  AND  CAPITAL  AREA 

A  significant  interrelationship  exists  between  the  core  area  of  a  country 
and  the  location  of  its  capital.  But,  as  is  pointed  out  above,  to  focus  on  the 
capital  city  of  a  country  provides  only  a  preliminary  identification  of  its 
core  area.  In  the  following  discussion  an  attempt  is  made  to  trace  certain 
general  trends  as  they  reveal  themselves  in  the  comparison  of  capital  and 
core  areas.  Sometimes  the  two  are  identical.  Sometimes  the  initial  selection 
of  a  place  as  site  of  the  capital  results  in  the  consequent  growth  of  a  politi- 
cal, and  in  some  cases  also  of  an  economic  core  area.  In  other  instances  we 
find  that  a  new  political  and  economic  core  area  develops  at  a  distance 
from  the  capital  area.  Then  the  problem  arises  inevitably  as  to  whether 
intangible  factors,  such  as  tradition  and  prestige,  prove  strong  enough  to 
maintain  the  capital  location  at  its  original  place,  or  whether  the  centripe- 
tal forces  of  the  core  area  are  stronger  and  will  eventually  result  in  the 
shift  of  the  capital  to  a  new  site.  The  following  discussion  is  limited  to  a 
few  outstanding  examples  that  are  treated  in  terms  of  political  geography 
only.  The  reader  who  wishes  to  study  the  role  of  capital  cities  on  a  broader 
plane  and  in  its  historical  and  cultural  impacts  is  referred  to  the  stimulat- 
ing treatment  of  this  subject  by  A.  J.  Toynbee  in  A  Study  of  History.3 

1D.  Whittlesey,  The  Earth  and  the  State  (New  York,  1944),  pp.  2  and  597,  de- 
fine the  core  or  "nuclear"  core  as  "the  area  in  which  or  about  which  a  state  originates." 

2  W.  G.  East,  in  his  essay  on  "The  Nature  of  Political  Geography"  ( Politico,  1937, 
p.  273),  defines  therefore  the  core,  or  as  he  calls  it,  nuclear  region,  as  the  one  "which, 
lying  around  the  capital,  contains  the  major  endowment  of  the  state  in  respect  of 
population,  resources  and  political  energy." 

3  A.  I.  Toynbee,  A  Study  of  History,  Vol.  VII  (New  York,  1954),  pp.  193-239. 


144  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 


Fie.  6-1.  The  Shifting  Core  of  Turkey. 


SHIFT  OF  CAPITAL:   TURKEY 

In  contrast  to  the  situation  prevailing  during  World  War  II  when  the 
Soviet  government,  for  purely  military  reasons,  evacuated  Moscow  and 
made  Kuibyshev  the  temporary  capital,  we  observe  in  Turkey  the  genuine 
shift  of  a  capital  from  Istanbul  to  Ankara  where  the  government  of  Kemal 
Ataturk  moved  it.  A  provincial  city  began  immediately  to  develop  as  a 
focal  point  for  the  Turkish  Republic  4  ( Fig.  6-1 ) .  This  shift  can  only  in 
part  be  explained  by  what  appeared  to  be  an  arbitrary  decision  of  the 
government  to  remain  in  Ankara,  even  after  the  emergency  that  had 
caused  the  shift  had  passed.  The  real  reason  for  the  shift  must  be  seen  in 
the  fact  that  the  Straits  and  Istanbul  had  lost  many  of  the  factors  that  had 

4  See  E.  Fischer,  "Southern  Europe,"  in  G.  W.  Hoffman,  ed.,  A  Geography  of 
Europe  (New  York,  1954),  pp.  463-465. 


CORE  AREAS,  CAPITAL  CITIES,  COMMUNICATIONS  145 

made  them  the  core  of  the  old  Ottoman  Empire.  They  were  no  longer  in 
a  central  position  for  Turkey  (Fig.  6-1).  After  the  loss  of  the  European 
provinces  Istanbul's  bridge  position  was  of  no  peculiar  value.  The  impor- 
tant trade  between  the  Black  Sea  countries  and  the  Mediterranean  since 
antiquity  came  to  an  almost  complete  standstill  when  the  Bolshevist 
Revolution  had  replaced  a  wheat-exporting  Russia  by  a  Soviet  state  striv- 
ing for  autarchy.  Istanbul  had  never  been  a  manufacturing  center.  It  had 
been  a  gathering  point  for  all  the  nations  of  the  Ottoman  Empire  and  had 
a  very  strong  Greek  element.  This  had  been  an  advantage  for  the  Ottoman 
Empire,  which  used  Turks  as  soldiers  and  governors  but  filled  many  ad- 
ministrative positions  with  Greeks  and  Armenians.  This  national  composi- 
tion made  Istanbul  unfit  to  serve  as  the  core  of  a  national  Turkish  state. 
When  Ankara  was  chosen  as  its  capital,  a  number  of  favorable  factors 
contributed  to  the  development  of  a  new  core.  It  was  in  the  approximate 
center  of  the  state,  in  an  area  of  pure  Turkish  population.  To  this  were 
added  the  governmental  functions,  and  gradually  some  industry,  and  rail- 
road and  road  connections  were  established  in  all  directions. 


LACK  OF  IDENTITY  BETWEEN  POLITICAL  CORE  AND 
CAPITAL:  THE  GROWTH  OF  WASHINGTON,  D.C. 

We  find  in  the  example  of  Istanbul  and  Ankara  almost  all  of  the  features 
which  are  the  characteristics  of  a  political  core.  These  stress  the  degree 
to  which  a  capital  can  serve  as  the  indication  of  a  political  core.  However, 
not  every  capital  is  the  real  core  of  a  country.  Newly-founded  capitals 
may  need  a  long  time  to  attract  other  than  purely  governmental  functions. 
An  outstanding  example  is  the  development  of  Washington.  It  is  obvious 
that  in  a  federal  state  the  functions  of  the  federal  government  are  of  less 
importance  than  in  a  centralized  state.  Therefore,  the  influence  of  the 
governmental  functions  in  creating  a  political  core  area  is  less  in  a  federal 
state.  Washington's  growth  as  a  political  center  was  retarded  by  these 
factors,  until  during  World  War  I,  and  later,  especially  under  the  New 
Deal,  the  functions  of  the  federal  government  grew  in  size  and  impor- 
tance. Never  before  had  the  central  direction  of  the  armed  forces  played 
such  a  role.  Furthermore,  because  of  the  relatively  small  influence  Ameri- 
can naval  or  military  power  exerted  upon  relations  with  other  countries, 
the  actual  influence  the  United  States  exerted  abroad  had  little  to  do  with 
a  power-backed  foreign  policy.  This  influence  originated  rather  from  the 
growing  economic  power  of  the  United  States  and  because  it  had  become 
the  principal  haven  for  immigrants.  Consequently,  the  area  of  highest 


146  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

political  power,  the  political  core,  was  not  centered  in  the  capital  but  in 
the  area  of  the  most  intensive  economic  activity,  in  the  coastal  belt  extend- 
ing from  southern  New  England  to  Baltimore.  This  was  also  the  area 
where  many  products  of  other  regions  converged  for  export,  where  the 
immigrants  landed  and  a  large  proportion  of  them  stayed,  and  where  the 
population  was  the  densest. 


STABILITY  OF  CAPITAL  LOCATION  IN  THE  LIGHT 
OF  POLITICAL  CHANGES 

One  major  reason  for  the  original  selection  of  Washington  as  the  capital 
site  was  its  central  location  between  the  northern  and  southern  states. 
With  the  expansion  of  the  United  States  westward  and,  at  the  same  time, 
with  the  rapid  increase  of  population  in  the  north,  Washington  lost  this 
locational  advantage.  Yet  no  shift  of  the  capital  was  contemplated  be- 
cause a  capital  has  the  tendency  to  remain  in  the  place  where  it  was 
founded.  This  is  partly  a  matter  of  convenience  and  the  costs  involved  in 
the  abandonment  of  buildings  designed  for  special  purposes  with  the  re- 
sulting necessity  of  erecting  new  ones;  mostly,  however,  it  is  due  to  tradi- 
tion and  prestige.  Rome,  Jerusalem,  and  Mecca  are  prime  examples.  Mecca 
has  nothing  to  recommend  it  except  its  religious  significance.  It  is  at  pres- 
ent only  the  second  capital  of  Saudi  Arabia  and  shares  the  capital  position 
with  the  more  centrally  located  Riyadh.  Mecca  emerged  from  periods  of 
obscurity  several  times  in  its  long  history  for  no  other  apparent  reason 
than  the  intangible  impact  of  its  tradition.  It  is  a  moot  question  whether 
Rome  would  have  been  selected  as  the  capital  of  an  Italian  national  state 
except  for  its  tradition  as  the  seat  of  the  Roman  Empire  and  the  Papacy. 
In  these  eighty-odd  years  since  it  became  the  capital  of  Italy  it  has  in- 
creased in  stature,  but  not  solely  by  reason  of  the  concentration  of  govern- 
ment functions.  It  became  one  of  the  foci  of  the  Italian  railroad  system, 
though  Milan  and  perhaps  some  other  cities  are  rivaling  its  importance  in 
this  respect.  Subsequently  Rome  has  become  a  seat  of  industry,  but  there 
is  still  little  indication  that  it  may  become  the  center  of  an  industrial  dis- 
trict, as  are  Turin  and  Genoa.5 

Still  more  significant  is  the  case  of  Jerusalem.  The  capital  of  the  revived 

5  According  to  official  Italian  statistics,  Rome's  population  has  more  than  doubled 
since  1921,  when  it  was  692,000.  It  has  increased  ten  times  since  1850,  when  it  was 
175,000.  It  totaled  1,791,000  in  1954,  and  is  approaching  the  2,000,000  mark  which 
it  reached  at  the  height  of  the  Roman  Empire  when  it  was  the  political,  economic,  and 
social  capital  not  only  of  the  Mediterranean  areas  but  likewise  of  the  western  world, 
including  a  Transalpine  annex  extending  to  the  Rhine  and  the  Tyne. 


CORE  AREAS,  CAPITAL  CITIES,  COMMUNICATIONS  147 


Fig.  6-2.  The  Core  Area  of  Israel. 


Jewish  state  of  Israel  is  located  in  the  new  part  of  the  city,  which  has  no 
real  tradition.  Its  historical  prestige  is  derivative.  It  is  located  on  the  tip 
of  a  salient,  surrounded  on  three  sides  by  hostile  Jordan  territory,  cut  off 
from  possible  trade  routes  and  even  from  a  local  trade  area.  Industry  is 
little  developed  and  that  in  existence  is  an  artificial  growth  fostered  for 
political  reasons.  To  speak  of  Jerusalem  as  a  core  area  is  only  possible  in 
a  psychological  sense  because  of  the  emotional  appeal  to  the  Israelis  as 


148  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

well  as  to  the  Jewish  and  to  the  Christian  world  outside.  The  center  of 
economic  activity  is  the  coastal  strip  between  Haifa  and  Tel  Aviv;  here 
we  find  the  actual  core  of  the  country  ( Fig.  6-2 ) . 

These  examples  show  also  that  the  core  area  of  a  country  or  a  state  is 
not  necessarily  its  administrative  center  nor  its  area  of  origin.  The  Italian 
example  is  one  among  several  others  which  demonstrate  that  a  country 
is  not  necessarily  limited  to  one  core  area. 

THE  RUSSIAN  CAPITALS 

While  the  examples  discussed  above  point  to  the  stabilizing  influence  of 
intangible  factors,  such  as  tradition  and  prestige,  which  account  for  the 
continuation  of  the  capital  at  its  ancient  site  in  spite  of  drastic  political 
and  economic  changes  in  the  domain  of  the  country,  we  find  in  contrast 
instances  where  ideological  factors  and  changes  motivated  a  shift  of  the 
capital.  Ideological  factors,  more  than  any  other,  have  determined  the 
designation  of  capitals  in  Russia  and  the  Soviet  Union.  The  capital  which 
Peter  the  Great  laid  out  in  1703  (St.  Petersburg)  close  to  the  Baltic  Sea 
as  a  window  to  the  West,  and  the  transfer  of  the  seat  of  government  from 
Moscow  in  the  heart  of  Russia,  gave  testimony  of  a  new  political  philoso- 
phy in  Russia  intent  on  opening  Russia  to  Western  cultural  influence.  In 
Toynbee's  words,6  "the  seat  of  government  of  a  landlocked  empire  was 
planted  in  a  remote  corner  of  the  empire's  domain  in  order  to  provide  the 
capital  with  easy  access  by  sea  to  the  sources  of  alien  civilization  which 
the  imperial  government  was  eager  to  introduce  -into  its  dominions." 
Peter's  decision  was,  as  Toynbee  puts  it  succinctly,  both  "spiritual  and 
geopolitical"  in  purpose.7  It  lasted  for  more  than  two  hundred  years. 
After  the  beginning  of  the  war  between  Germany  and  Russia  in  1914, 
St.  Petersburg  was  rechristened  Petrograd  in  an  outbreak  of  Slavophil 
nationalism,  only  to  be  renamed  Leningrad  in  1918  by  the  Bolsheviks. 
When  the  disciples  of  Lenin  transferred  the  capital  from  Leningrad  to 
Moscow,  they  were  motivated  not  only  by  the  more  conveniently  located 
site  for  the  administrative  capital  of  the  Soviet  Union  as  a  whole;  they 
also  intended  to  symbolize  the  break,  culturally  and  power-politically, 
between  the  Soviet  empire  and  the  West. 

6  Op.  cit.,  Vol.  VII,  p.  221;  see  also  pp.  222,  223;  690-691. 

7  Ibid.,  p.  238. 


CORE  AREAS,  CAPITAL  CITIES,  COMMUNICATIONS  149 

THE  "NATURAL"  CORE:  CENTRAL  AND 
PERIPHERAL  LOCATION 

In  some  countries  (such  as  France  and  Portugal  in  Europe,  Argentina, 
Uruguay,  and  Chile  in  South  America,  and  many  others)  there  exist 
relatively  simple  conditions  favoring  the  development  of  the  core  area. 
Paris  is  the  undisputed  center  of  French  intellectual  and  social  life; 
Paris  and  the  He  de  France  have  been  France's  political  center  for 
many  centuries;  Paris  is  by  far  the  largest  city  of  France.  Furthermore, 
the  main  industrial  and  mining  districts  of  France  are  practically  adjoin- 
ing. All  this  makes  the  north  and  northwest  of  France  together  with  Paris 
the  core  area  of  this  country  8  (cf.  Fig.  6-7,  p.  159).  This  also  indicates 
that  a  core  area  is  not  necessarily  in  the  center  of  a  country,  though  such 
a  location  undoubtedly  favors  the  development  of  a  core  area. 

Peripheral  location  of  a  core  area  is  especially  frequent  among  seafar- 
ing nations.  Lisbon  in  Portugal,  and  London  in  the  British  Isles  are  ex- 
amples. Where  the  adjacent  sea  represents  one  major  field  of  economic 
activity  of  a  nation,  such  a  location  of  a  capital  and  core  area  may  be  even 
more  significant  than  a  central  position. 

LATIN  AMERICAN  CORE  AREAS 

Slightly  different  is  the  case  of  those  South  American  countries  that 
were  mentioned  before.  Their  capitals  and  the  core  areas  surrounding 
them  are  the  points  of  entry  into  these  countries  and  still  mirror  the  history 
of  colonization  ( Fig.  6-3 ) .  In  general  it  is  true  that  other  parts  of  a  coun- 
try are  the  less  advanced  the  farther  they  are  from  these  points.  In  the 
areas  of  old  Indian  civilizations,  the  capitals  of  Spanish  vice-royalties  and 
audiencias,  and  later  of  the  independent  states,  tended  to  replace  old  In- 
dian centers,  or  at  least  to  stay  in  the  areas  of  population  agglomeration. 
These  core  areas  are  still  surrounded  by  areas  of  very  sparse  population. 
Thus  Quito,  Bogota,  and  Mexico  City  became  capitals  of  Ecuador,  Co- 
lombia, and  Mexico.9  In  Peru,  Lima,  the  city  near  the  port  of  entry,  be- 
came predominant  over  the  older  capital,  Cuzco,  situated  centrally  in  the 
densely  inhabited  Indian  highland.  However,  in  the  other  countries,  in 
Brazil,  Argentina,  Chile,  Paraguay  and  Venezuela,  and  in  almost  all  of  the 
Central  American  countries,  the  capitals  are  the  center  of  the  only,  or 

8  Whittlesey,  op.  cit.,  p.  429.  His  discussions  of  other  capitals  are  scattered  through- 
out the  book. 

9  P.  E.  James,  Latin  America  (New  York  and  Boston,  1942),  p.  4. 


Cayenne 


Georgetown 

iramaribo 

BR.  GUIANA  / 


Rio  de  Janeiro 


200  400  600  Ml 


J.R.F. 


Fig.  6-3.  Population  Centers  of  South  America. 
150 


CORE  AREAS,  CAPITAL  CITIES,  COMMUNICATIONS  151 

the  predominant,  population  cluster  and  the  boundaries,  with  only  few 
exceptions,10  are  laid  in  the  extremely  sparsely  populated  zones. 

STATE  CAPITALS  IN  THE  UNITED  STATES 

It  is  interesting  to  compare  with  this  development  the  history  of  many 
of  the  thirteen  original  states  of  the  United  States.  The  capitals  and  core 
areas  of  the  thirteen  states  were  originally  the  points  of  entry,  and,  there- 
fore, with  the  exception  of  Hartford,  Connecticut,  port  cities.  When  the 
territories  of  the  states  filled  up,  the  capitals  moved  in  many  cases  to  some 
central  location  in  the  state.  It  is  rather  an  exception  that  Boston,  because  of 
its  predominance  in  the  small  Commonwealth  of  Massachusetts,  retained 
its  capital  position.  Neither  New  York  nor  Philadelphia  continued  as  capi- 
tal cities.  Annapolis,  still  the  capital  of  Maryland,  is  rather  atypical.  It 
certainly  does  not  indicate  the  core  area  of  the  state. 

INDIA  AND  AUSTRALIA 

In  India  the  shift  of  the  capital  from  Calcutta  to  New  Delhi  in  1911,  the 
creation  for  this  area  of  a  separate  status  resembling  that  of  the  District 
of  Columbia  by  the  Government  of  India  Act  in  1935,  and  the  sudden  and 
tremendous  increase  of  population  of  the  twin  cities  Delhi  and  New  Delhi 
after  1941,  all  signify  the  progress  from  a  British  colony,  ruled  from  across 
the  sea,  to  a  self-governing  political  body  and  final  independence.11  Here 
the  political  power  can  no  longer  be  exerted  from  the  periphery. 

In  Australia,  the  realization  that  the  interests  of  a  federated  state  would 
be  better  served  by  a  capital  near  the  anticipated  population  center  of  the 
country  than  by  one  in  a  peripheral  location  led  to  the  selection  of  Can- 
berra instead  of  one  of  the  coastal  state  capitals  when  the  six  colonies 
formed  the  Commonwealth  in  1901  (cf.  Fig.  2-10,  p.  49). 

BRAZIL  AND  ARGENTINA 

In  Brazil,  quite  similar  considerations  have  prompted  plans  to  shift  the 
capital  from  Rio  de  Janeiro  on  the  coast  to  a  central  inland  location.  The 
new  site  has  been  blueprinted  on  the  watershed  between  the  Amazon  and 
the  Parana,  in  a  region  rich  in  mineral  resources  and  coffee  plantations; 
but  it  remains  to  be  seen  whether  the  growth  and  concentration  of  eco- 

10  Ibid.,  James  names  the  boundaries  between  Venezuela  and  Colombia,  Colombia 
and  Ecuador,  and  Peru  and  Bolivia  as  the  only  ones  which  run  through  population 
clusters. 

11  O.  H.  K.  Spate,  Geography  of  India  and  Pakistan  (London,  1954),  pp.  491-493. 


152 


THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 


Fig.  6-4.  Brazil:  Shift  of  Capitals. 

nomic  interests  in  the  interior  will  prove  strong  enough  to  unseat  Rio  as 
capital12  (Fig.  6-4).  Such  a  change  is  characteristic  of  a  dynamic  and 
growing  new  nation  and  is  not  without  historical  precedent  in  Brazil. 
Brazil's  first  capital  was  Salvador,  located  near  the  easternmost  point  of 
land  in  the  state  of  Bahia.  Salvador  was  founded  in  1510  and  remained 
the  capital  of  Brazil  until  1792,  when  the  shift  of  economic  interests 
southward  led  to  the  selection  of  Rio  as  capital,  about  midway  along 
the  coastline. 

In  contrast  to  the  changing  fortunes  of  the  political  and  economic  core 
areas  in  Brazil,  Argentina's  capital,  Buenos  Aires,  has  maintained  its  rank- 
since  1580,  showing  a  phenomenal  growth  in  the  last  150  years  (1800: 
30,000;  1950:  3,445,000).  The  vision  and  geographical  sense  of  Don  Juan 

12  In  this  connection,  it  is  interesting  to  compare  the  population  growth  of  Rio  de 
Janeiro  from  1,787,000  in  1940  to  2,600,000  in  1954  with  that  of  Sao  Paulo,  during 
the  same  period,  from  1,323,000  to  2,500,000. 


CORE  AREAS,  CAPITAL  CITIES,  COMMUNICATIONS  153 

de  Garay  who  resettled  the  deserted  town  of  Nuestra  Senora  Maria  de 
Buen  Aire  in  1580  accounts  for  Buenos  Aires'  safe  position  as  the  country's 
core  over  the  centuries,  for  he  understood  that  not  gold  and  silver  but  the 
agricultural  wealth  of  the  city's  hinterland  assured  its  future.  Although  his 
party  consisted  of  only  66  persons,  de  Garay  drew  plans  for  a  metropolis 
large  enough  to  house  4,000,000  inhabitants.13 

SPAIN 

The  political  function  of  Madrid  accounts  predominantly  for  its  position 
as  the  core  of  Spain.  This  is  an  especially  striking  example  that  the  politi- 
cal core  does  not  necessarily  coincide  with  the  economic  core  or  a  central 
population  cluster.  Areas  of  higher  economic  importance,  denser  popula- 
tion, and,  even  more  significant,  very  old  tradition  of  political  importance, 
are  ruled  from  this  center.  These  other  areas  are  handicapped  by  their 
excentric  and  more  or  less  isolated  location,  and  by  their  different  lan- 
guages (Basque,  Catalan)  or  dialects  (Andalusia,  Asturias,  Galicia).  These 
factors  would  hinder  any  attempt  by  such  areas  to  become  the  political 
core  of  Spain.  The  most  they  could  strive  for,  and  for  which  all  except 
Andalusia  challenged  the  core  area  in  the  Civil  War,  is  some  status  of 
autonomy.  In  this  they  have  been  thwarted.  The  only  principal  area 
which,  on  the  strength  of  firmly  embedded  traditions,  retained  its  inde- 
pendence from  Madrid  and  Castile  is  Portugal. 

CHINA 

If  potential  core  areas  are  more  equally  balanced,  the  outcome  may  be 
different.  In  China  three  core  areas  have  been  the  seat  of  capitals  14  (Fig. 
6-5)  the  Wei  valley,  the  Yangtse  valley,  and  northeast  China.  The  Wei 
valley,  where  Sian  (today  called  Changan)  is  located  was  placed  most 
favorably  in  a  China  which  neither  included  all  of  South  China  nor  large 
parts  of  the  coasts.  Capitals  in  the  Yangtse  valley  were  characteristic  for 
periods  when  the  north  was  either  lost  to  inner-Asiatic  conquerors  or  the 
south  could  assert  its  preponderance  for  other  reasons.   Hankow   and 
Nanking  have  been  capitals  in  the  past  and  again  for  short  periods  in  the 
seesaw  battle  of  opposing  forces  in  twentieth  century  China.  Nanking  as 
capital  has  not  only  historical  associations  but  as  a  harbor  city  symbolized 
also  the  connection  with  the  western  powers.  Places  still  farther  away,  on 
Formosa  or  even  the  important  city  of  Canton,  have  never  been  nor  are 
likely  to  become  more  than  local  centers.  In  the  north  Peiping  (Peking) 

13  F.  A.  Carlson,  Geography  of  Latin  America  (New  York,  1952),  p.  153. 

14  W.  G.  East  and  O.  H.  K.  Spate,  The  Changing  Map  of  Asia,  2nd  ed.  (New  York, 
1953),  pp.  270-272. 


_, — 

♦ 

r 

w 

Peiping  ( Peking);/ 


11 


Changan  (Sian) 


ISLANDS 


Fig.  6-5.  Capitals  of  China. 


154 


CORE  AREAS,  CAPITAL  CITIES,  COMMUNICATIONS  155 


Fig.  6-6.  Core  Areas  of  Japan  according  to  Population  Density  per  Square  Kilometer: 
(1)  over  625;  (2)  210-625;  (3)  130-210;  (4)  70-130. 

represents  the  opposite  principle  to  that  represented  by  Nanking.  At  all 
periods  it  emphasized  the  predominance  of  Chinese  interests  in  Central 
Asia  and  the  prevalence  of  influences  originating  there  or  working 
through  Central  Asia,  as  at  present  from  Soviet  Asia.  This  is  the  more 
remarkable,  as  Peking  is  not  located  on  a  geometrically  straight  route  to 
Central  Asia,  but  on  a  dominant  point  of  the  circuitous  route  which  leads 
from  China  to  Central  Asian  centers  without  having  to  cross  a  desert. 
This  location  makes  Peking  a  convenient  capital  for  a  Communist  China. 
Chinese  westernization  had  caused  industrial  centers  to  mushroom  in  the 
coastal  cities,  Shanghai,  Canton,  and  Nanking.  The  direct  result  of  the 
new  industrial  developments  in  the  north  and  in  regions  which  are  acces- 
sible to  the  Soviet  borders  has  been  that  the  older  industrial  centers  along 
the  coast  of  southeastern  China  have  practically  ceased  to  function.15 


JAPAN 

In  Japan,  the  transfer  of  the  capital  in  1868  from  Kyoto,  for  many  cen- 
turies the  country's  major  city  in  the  west,  to  Tokyo  or,  as  it  was  then 

15  C.  M.  Chang,  "Five  Years  of  Communist  Rule  in  China,"  Foreign  Affairs  ( 1954), 
pp.  98-110  (109);  see  also  R.  Murphy,  "The  City  as  a  Center  of  Change:  Western 
Europe  and  China,"  Annals  of  the  Association  of  American  Geographers  (1954),  pp. 
349-369  (360-361). 


156  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

called,  Yedo,  on  the  shores  of  Yedo  Bay  in  the  east,  symbolized  the  end  of 
Japan's  feudal  isolation  and  the  nation's  readiness  to  embark  on  its  new 
course  as  a  world  power  16  (Fig.  6-6).  In  the  Kwanto  plain,  with  its  twin 
cities  of  Tokyo  and  Yokohama,  in  a  core  area  of  only  5,000  square  miles, 
fifteen  million  people  or  less  than  one-fifth  of  Japan's  population  is  now 
concentrated. 

GERMANY 

An  interesting  competition  between  rival  core  areas  for  the  location  of 
the  capital  is  under  way  in  Germany.  It  is  overshadowed  by  the  numerous 
and  more  pressing  problems  of  today's  East-West  struggle  but  is  still 
clearly  recognizable.  Throughout  many  centuries  Germany  had  no  politi- 
cal core,  and  economically  the  Rhine  core  area  was  only  ill-defined.17  In 
the  Middle  Ages  kings  and  emperors  came  from  different  parts  of  Ger- 
many and  moved  with  their  courts  from  castle  to  castle  and  from  city  to 
city.  When  the  Hapsburgs  established  a  semi-inheritance  of  the  crown, 
their  residence,  Vienna,  could  not  qualify  as  a  core  area  for  Germany  be- 
cause of  its  excentric  location.18  When  in  the  nineteenth  century  the  kings 
of  Prussia  succeeded  in  uniting  Germany,  their  capital  Berlin  dominated 
Prussia  politically,  while  the  lower  Rhine  valley  around  Cologne  and 
Diisseldorf  and  the  Ruhr  area  had  many  characteristics  of  a  true  economic 
core  area  but  lacked  political  tradition.  In  the  German  Empire  politically 
favorable  conditions  tended  to  strengthen  Berlin's  position.  Not  only  did 
its  administrative  functions  increase  strongly  with  the  centralization  cul- 
minating under  Hitler;  a  railroad  net  focusing  in  Berlin  was  constructed; 
more  and  more  banks  established  their  main  offices  in  the  capital,  and 
many  flexible  industries  gravitated  to  Berlin  in  spite  of  its  rather  incon- 
venient location  in  the  northeast  of  the  Reich.  Today,  despite  all  that  has 
happened,  Berlin  is  still  regarded  as  the  "natural"  capital  of  Germany.  It 
may  be  made  the  capital  again  as  soon  as  Germany  is  reunited.  Therefore, 
attempts  are  made  19  to  prove  the  continuing  core  function  of  Berlin,  even 
though  its  location  in  present  Germany  would  be  very  close  to  what  is 
now  the  Polish  boundary  on  the  Neisse  and  Oder  rivers  (cf.  Fig.  4-10, 
p.  108). 

16  G.  B.  Cressey,  Asia's  Lands  and  People,  2nd  ed.  (1951),  pp.  210-216  (map); 
East  and  Spate,  op.  cit.,  pp.  298,  299;  see  also  Toynbee,  op.  cit.,  Vol.  7,  pp.  220-221. 

17  R.  E.  Dickinson,  Germany  (Syracuse,  N.  Y.,  1953),  passim. 

18  Today,  Vienna's  role  as  the  core  of  Austria,  is  illustrated  by  the  fact  that  one- 
fourth  of  its  population  of  7,000,000  is  concentrated  in  the  capital. 

19  Institut  fiir  Raumforschung,  Bonn  (ed.),  Die  iinzerstorbare  Stadt  (Cologne- 
Berlin,  1953). 


CORE  AREAS,  CAPITAL  CITIES,  COMMUNICATIONS  157 

When  the  question  of  the  seat  of  government  for  West  Germany  was 
decided,  Bonn  won  over  Frankfurt.  Frankfurt  is  much  more  centrally  lo- 
cated between  north  and  south  and  is  an  important  communications  cen- 
ter; it  is  also  the  center  of  an  economically  important  district.  Frankfurt 
even  has  a  political  tradition  as  the  long-time  coronation  city  of  the  First 
Empire  and  the  seat  of  its  impotent  diet.  For  all  these  reasons  it  was  feared 
that  if  Frankfurt  were  made  temporary  capital  it  might  become  a  serious 
rival  for  Berlin  after  reunion.  Bonn,  on  the  other  hand,  was  clearly  a  place- 
holder for  Berlin.  A  small  university  town  without  much  economic  ac- 
tivity, adjacent  to  but  outside  of  the  Cologne-Ruhr  area,  it  could  not 
seriously  threaten  Berlin's  expected  reappearance  as  capital.20 

LOCATION  OF  CAPITALS  NEAR  FRONTIERS 

Some  political  geographers  have  noted  the  position  of  several  capitals 
near  a  frontier  of  conquest  or  also  near  an  endangered  frontier.  Berlin, 
Vienna,  and  Peking  have  been  named  in  this  connection.  Location  near 
a  frontier  may  have  been  an  advantage  in  an  era  of  slow  communications. 
It  is  a  distinct  disadvantage  in  the  era  of  mobile  and  air  warfare.  So  far 
only  the  Soviet  Union  and  Turkey,  have  removed  their  capitals  perma- 
nently from  an  endangered  frontier  to  a  safer  place;  in  other  cases  the 
factors  favoring  permanence,  especially  ideological  factors,  have  defeated 
those  favoring  change. 

THE  EFFECT  OF  COMMUNICATIONS  NETS  ON  CORE  AREAS 

A  core  area  as  an  area  where  the  political  power  of  a  state  is  concen- 
trated requires  the  means  to  make  its  influence  felt  in  the  other  parts  of 
the  political  body.  It  needs  a  well-developed  communications  net.  Stu- 
dents of  transportation  geography  have  been  primarily  concerned  with  the 
economic  aspects  of  communications;  the  political  and  power  aspects  have 
been  treated  only  incidentally.  Without  a  properly  developed  system  of 
communications  the  prolonged  existence  of  a  territorial  state— as  opposed 
to  a  tribal  territory,  a  feudal  agglomeration,  or  a  city-state— is  almost  im- 
possible. It  is  a  common  characteristic  of  most  ancient  states  that  they 
were  strung  out  along  rivers— the  Nile,  Tigris,  Euphrates,  Indus,  Wei,  and 
Hoang-ho.  It  was  much  later  that  ocean  shipping  was  developed  enough 
to  allow  the  existence  of  coast-based  or  circum-marine  states.  The  Athe- 
nian and  the  Roman  empires  are  the  best  known  examples,  although  older 

20  See  also  p.  156. 


158  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

ones,  like  the  Cretan  and  Carthaginian,  have  existed.  Roads,  designed 
from  the  beginning  for  military  purposes  and  administrative  efficiency, 
were  built  in  the  Persian  Empire,  and  brought  to  a  stage  of  perfection  in 
the  Roman  Empire  unequaled  until  modern  times.  The  flagstone  trails  and 
canals  of  the  Chinese  Empire  and  the  roads  of  the  Incas  should  also  be 
mentioned  in  this  context. 

Compared  with  these  long-lived  and  well-organized  empires  most  other 
great  states  of  the  past  have  been  either  short-lived,  such  as  the  Mongolian 
Empire,  or  they  were  so  loosely  organized  and  their  communications 
systems  so  disintegrated  that  their  activities  as  consolidated  units  in  re- 
lation to  other  powers  evolved  only  in  rare  instances  and  after  long  pe- 
riods; the  medieval  states  of  France  or  Germany  are  good  examples.  Or 
they  had  to  be  reconstructed  periodically  because  of  the  continuous  proc- 
ess of  disintegration— such  a  state  was  the  Assyrian  kingdom,  whose  kings 
were  continuously  on  the  warpath  in  order  to  exact  overdue  tributes,  sub- 
due rebellious  vassals,  and  re-establish  their  control.  This  type  of  empire 
has  survived  in  a  few  instances  into  the  twentieth  century.  To  the  very 
eve  of  the  conquest  by  Italy,  the  rulers  of  Ethiopia  were  wont  to  send 
tax-gathering  and  punitive  expeditions  into  such  outlying  areas  as  the 
Ogaden  and  Kaffa.  Sinkiang,  formerly  called  Chinese  Turkestan,  had  to 
be  reconquered  time  and  again.  It  has  been  estimated  that  out  of  about 
2,000  years  of  Chinese  rule,  this  control  was  effective  only  approximately 
425  years.21 

The  significance  and  importance  of  paved  roads  for  the  stability  of 
states  has  changed  only  slowly  since  antiquity.  The  compass,  sea  charts, 
and  nautical  instruments,  together  with  developments  in  ship  designs, 
enabled  not  only  the  great  discoveries  since  the  sixteenth  century,  but  also 
the  establishment  of  far-flung  colonial  empires.  Besides  these  forms  older 
ones  persisted  and  until  the  second  half  of  the  nineteenth  century  Russian 
rule  in  Siberia,  and  also  Canada's  development,  were  based  on  river  navi- 
gation by  small  vessels,  supplemented  by  portages. 

Hard-surfaced  roads— the  chaussees  of  the  French  (Fig.  6-7 ) —railroads, 
canals,  and  ocean  highways  are  among  the  indispensable  bases  of  the 
modern  state.  The  twentieth  century  has  added  the  internal-combustion 
engine  and  its  use  in  the  automobile  and  the  airplane. 

This  short  historical  review  permits  the  conclusion  that  small  states  are 
far  less  dependent  on  internal  communications  than  are  large  ones.  Within 

21  O.  Lattimore,  Inner  Asian  Frontiers  of  China,  American  Geographical  Society 
Research  Series  No.  21,  1940,  p.  171. 


CORE  AREAS,  CAPITAL  CITIES,  COMMUNICATIONS  159 


BELGIUM  l^  - 

IV  U 


7  V.       J   LUXEMBOURG 


GERMANY 


Brest 


Mulhouse  1  /  O"*— • 


ATLANTIC 
OCEAN 


200  Mi  "^■•— I        -v.^ 

23  SPAIN  *-* 


MEDITERRANEAN 


Fig.  6-7.  Post  Roads  of  France. 


the  latter,  the  political  core  is  strong  only  if  it  is  served  adequately  by 
communications.  We  must  distinguish  between  the  economic  and  political 
functions  of  the  communications  net  within  a  core  area  and  those  connect- 
ing it  with  other  parts  of  the  body  politic.  In  the  Ruhr  area,  in  England's 
"black  country,"  in  the  area  extending  between  Baltimore  and  Boston,  the 
road,  railroad,  and  in  places  the  canal  net  is  very  dense;  indeed  these  areas 
could  not  exist  as  economic  centers  without  this  highly  developed  trans- 
portation network.  On  the  other  hand,  Madrid  in  Spain,  or  Ankara  in 
Turkey,  are  in  the  centers  of  a  radiating  pattern  of  roads,  railroads,  tele- 
graph and  telephone  lines,  but  there  is  hardly  a  network,  except  the 
normal  communications  network  within  the  big  city. 

It  is  not  incidental  that  the  first  important  rail  line  in  Russia  linked 
St.  Petersburg  and  Moscow.  The  return  of  Moscow  to  its  role  as  seat  of 
the  government  and  political  core  was  heralded  by  the  construction  of 
railroads  to  the  Volga  cities;  "they  soon  established  the  pattern  of  radiat- 


100            200  300  Mi 

— i  i 1         ' 


100     200     300    400  Km 


r~\ 


m. 


Fig.  6-8.  Railroad  Pattern  in  Western  Europe. 


160 


CORE  AREAS,  CAPITAL  CITIES,  COMMUNICATIONS  161 

ing  lines  centered  at  Moscow  which  became  the  dominant  feature  of  the 
pre-revolutionary  railroad  geography  of  the  country."  22  The  continuous 
extension  of  the  railroad  network  by  the  Soviet  government,  especially  the 
slowly  proceeding  eastward  extension,  has  not  altered  Moscow's  role  as 
the  main  hub  of  the  Soviet  Union  (cf.  Figs.  15-1,  15-2,  pp.  476,  478). 
Moscow's  core  quality  is  further  emphasized  by  its  strategical  location 
within  the  economic  core  area  fed  by  the  principal  inland  canals  of  the 
Soviet  Union:  the  Mariinsk  system,  the  Moscow  Canal,  and  the  White 
Sea-Baltic  Canal  (see  Fig.  8-7,  p.  238). 

The  radiating  communications  pattern  is  characteristic  for  a  political 
core  area.  A  highly  centralized  country  like  France  or  Great  Britain  shows 
this  pattern  in  perfect  form  ( Fig.  6-8 ) .  Berlin  and  Vienna  are  in  the  center 
of  radiating  communications  which,  however,  are  no  longer  congruent 
with  the  new  political  map.  When  after  World  War  I  new  states  emerged, 
their  political  problems  were  aggravated  by  the  incongruence  of  the  po- 
litical and  the  communication  patterns,  that  is,  the  lack  of  a  communica- 
tion system  focusing  upon  the  new  political  centers.  A  severe  case  of 
maladjustment  because  of  an  inherited  communication  system  developed 
in  Czechoslovakia  (Fig.  6-9).  The  railroads  and  roads  of  Moravia  and 
even  of  large  parts  of  Bohemia  had  been  constructed  for  easy  traffic  with 
Vienna.  Some  of  the  main  lines  by-passed  Prague,  the  capital,  at  a  short 
distance.  Slovakia's  railroads  and  roads  focused  on  Budapest,  the  capital 
of  Hungary,  and  were  only  tenuously  connected  with  Moravia  and 
Bohemia.  In  Yugoslavia  the  situation  was  even  worse.  In  order  to 
travel  from  the  capital,  Belgrade,  to  some  parts  of  the  country  detours 
were  necessary  which  more  than  doubled  the  actual  distance.  In  both 
cases,  but  especially  in  Yugoslavia,  the  problems  of  federalism,  and  of 
provincial  autonomy  versus  centralism,  were  aggravated  by  these  con- 
ditions. 

In  underdeveloped  countries  the  extent  of  backwardness  is  clearly  re- 
flected in  the  communications  net.  Neither  Brazil  nor  Colombia  has  a 
railroad  or  road  pattern  radiating  from  Rio  de  Janeiro  or  Bogota  ( cf.  Fig. 
22-2,  p.  674 ) .  Both  countries  have  suffered  from  recurring  revolts  originat- 
ing in  economically  advanced,  but  politically  not  well  integrated,  outlying 
areas.  Repeatedly  Sao  Paulo,  Rio  Grande  do  Sul,  Medellin,  or  Barranquilla 
refused  to  accept  the  policy  decreed  at  the  political  center.  Large  parts  of 
the  Amazonian  lowlands  belong  still  only  nominally  to  Brazil,  Bolivia, 
Peru,  or  Colombia.  Some  of  their  Indian  tribes  have  never  heard  the  name 
of  the  country  to  which  they  supposedly  belong.  The  advent  of  the  air- 

22  T.  Shabad,  pp.  82-92  (83). 


s 

JO 

ca 

S 

— 

o 

fa 


o 


« 

o 
u 

s 

u 


if 
C 


V 

#> 
u 

as 

0) 

s 


CD 

CO 

u 

— 

fa 


162 


CORE  AREAS,  CAPITAL  CITIES,  COMMUNICATIONS  163 

plane  has,  however,  strengthened  the  influence  of  the  central  authority. 

Generalized  maps,  as  small-scale  maps  necessarily  are,  sometimes  give 
only  an  inadequate  picture  of  the  actual  conditions.  On  a  small-scale  map 
France  seems  to  be  covered  with  a  web  of  lines,  with  Paris  clearly  in  the 
center.  Adequate  provisions  for  direct  connections  between  the  provincial 
centers  apparently  exist.  But  this  picture  is  deceiving,  because  the  traffic 
on  most  of  these  lines  is  slow,  trains  are  infrequent,  and  through-trains 
are  not  everywhere  available.  A  road  map  shows  the  generally  better  qual- 
ity of  the  roads  focusing  on  Paris  and  the  secondary  character  of  most 
others.  Similar  maps  of  Germany  would  not  easily  and  unmistakably  re- 
veal the  political  core  of  the  country.  They  would  indicate  several  centers, 
among  them  Cologne,  Halle  and  Leipzig,  Frankfurt  am  Main,  all  of  them 
as  prominent  as  Berlin.  The  first  three  places  are  also  in  the  midst  of  a 
very  dense  local  pattern,  the  sign  of  an  economic  concentration,  while  an 
analogous  pattern  is  absent  from  the  Berlin  area,  indicating  its  predomi- 
nantly political  role.  A  similar  picture  emerges  on  a  communications  map 
of  Italy.  The  dense  network  in  the  Turin-Milan-Genoa  triangle,  and  in  a 
second  triangle,  Verona-Venice-Bologna,  is  clearly  distinguished  from  the 
radial  pattern  of  Rome,  which  is  the  political  core. 

In  the  United  States,  Chicago  is  far  more  important  in  terms  of  its  com- 
munications pattern  than  Washington.  Cleveland,  New  York,  Philadel- 
phia, Omaha,  and  several  other  places  are  at  a  par  or  ahead  of  Washing- 
ton. Somewhat  different  is  the  pattern  in  Great  Britain.  London,  being  a 
great  economic  center  as  well  as  the  political  core,  dominates  Great  Brit- 
ain's communications  system. 

SHIPPING  LANES  AND  CORE  AREAS 

The  picture  would  be  incomplete  without  the  shipping  lanes.  Once  one 
includes  them  in  the  consideration,  the  routes  between  ports  of  the 
United  Kingdom  are  not  very  prominent.  However,  the  shipping  lanes 
and  also  the  air  routes  from  other  countries  lead  to  a  number  of  British 
ports  and,  though  London  is  the  most  frequented,  the  general  pattern  is 
not  that  of  focusing  on  London  (Fig.  6-10).  Rather  Great  Britain  as  a 
whole  appears  as  the  core  of  the  Commonwealth.  It  may  be  useful  to  dis- 
tinguish between  several  types  of  routes  radiating  from  the  ports  of  the 
United  Kingdom.  There  are  those  which  serve  only  or  primarily  commer- 
cial interests.  The  routes  to  the  United  States  and  most  of  the  routes  to  the 
European  continent  belong  in  this  category.  Other  routes  serve  both  polit- 
ical and  economic  interests  and  it  would  be  difficult  to  separate  those 


o 

a. 

£ 

o 
-o 
ec 

s 


'2 

a 

o 

h 
<*« 

M 

C 


« 

m 

Vi 

s 

c 
"5. 
.& 

CD 
© 

l-H 
■ 

u 


164 


CORE  AREAS,  CAPITAL  CITIES,  COMMUNICATIONS  165 

functions.  The  routes  across  the  Atlantic  to  Bermuda  and  Canada  exem- 
plify such  a  composite  function,  with  the  economic  function  prevailing. 
The  route  through  the  Gulf  of  Biscay  a,  the  Strait  of  Gibraltar,  the  Med- 
iterranean Sea,  and  the  Suez  Canal  to  Southern  and  Eastern  Asia  and 
Australia  has  often  been  called  the  lifeline  of  the  Commonwealth,  stress- 
ing thereby  its  political  function.  The  alternate  line  around  the  Cape  has 
had  its  phases  of  strength  and  weakness;  it  showed  strength  especially 
when  political  considerations  made  it  appear  safer  than  the  Suez  Canal 
route. 

Another  group  of  routes  would  never  have  come  into  existence  if  not  for 
political  reasons,  though  economic  interests  may  be  served.  The  economic 
functions,  however,  are  clearly  incidental.  This  is  especially  obvious  in  the 
case  of  analogous  shipping  services  of  other  powers.  Why  should  a  French 
line  extend  to  Madagascar,  Martinique,  or  Guadeloupe,  a  Portuguese  to 
Angola,  a  Belgian  to  Matadi  on  the  mouth  of  the  Congo,  if  not  because  of 
the  political  affiliations  of  these  countries?  The  fact  that  there  is  no  regular 
established  service  between  Portugal  and  Goa  or  Macao  is  anomalous. 

On  the  other  hand,  a  number  of  world  routes  are  frequented  by 
vessels  under  many  flags  and  are  thereby  of  major  importance  in  inter- 
national trade  relations.  Such  routes  are  the  transatlantic  routes  from 
the  ports  of  Western  Europe  to  North  America  and  also  to  South 
America.  The  Mediterranean  and  Suez  Canal  route  is  a  main  artery. 
So  is  the  route  through  the  Panama  Canal,  which  is  also  of  greatest  politi- 
cal and  military  significance  for  the  United  States.  When  the  construction 
of  the  Panama  Canal  was  undertaken,  President  Theodore  Roosevelt  sent 
the  American  fleet  on  a  world  cruise.  Its  first  lap  was  from  the  Atlantic 
Coast  around  Cape  Horn  to  the  Pacific  Coast  of  the  United  States,  dem- 
onstrating thereby  the  feasibility— and  the  disadvantages— of  this  world 
sea  route  and  the  strategic-political  importance  of  the  Panama  route. 

The  construction  of  major  canal  systems  leads  inevitably  to  significant 
dislocations  of  economic  and  political  core  areas.  We  can  anticipate  such 
changes  and  dislocations  within  the  United  States  and  Canada  upon  com- 
pletion of  the  St.  Lawrence  Seaway  (Fig.  6-11).  Involving  expenditures  of 
about  $300  million  to  provide  a  27-foot  deep  channel  from  the  Atlantic  to 
Lake  Ontario,  the  Seaway  is  scheduled  to  be  completed  in  1958.  The  bitter 
and  long  fight  which  preceded  the  agreement  between  the  United  States 
and  Canada  was  a  vivid  illustration  of  the  hopes  and  fears  expressed  by 
competing  coastal  and  port  areas  in  the  two  countries.  For  instance,  the 
port  director  of  Milwaukee,  the  waterborn  foreign  commerce  of  which 
totaled  in  1953  only  35,000  tons,  has  estimated  it  to  rise,  after  1958,  to 


166 


THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 


St  Louis 


Fig.  6-11.  The  St.  Lawrence  Seaway  and  the  American  Manufacturing  Belt. 

over  a  million  tons  annually,  while  the  port  director  of  New  York  fears  a 
loss  of  about  3,500,000  tons  a  year,  one-sixth  of  the  port's  foreign  com- 
merce in  general  cargo  and  grain.23 

The  Seaway  may  also  prevent  the  "American  Ruhr"  ( Detroit's  automo- 
bile industries,  Chicago's  farm  equipment  plants,  Milwaukee's  heavy  ma- 
chinery industries)  from  losing  its  economic  core  area  rank  as  the  result 
of  the  dwindling  of  its  iron  ore  reserves  in  the  mines  at  the  head  of  the 
lake  system  around  Lake  Superior.  With  the  completion  of  the  Seaway 
iron  ore  from  Labrador,  Quebec,  and  foreign  sources  could  be  supplied, 
and  at  competitive  prices.  The  serious  blow  which  the  Seaway  may  deal 
to  the  railways  in  the  eastern  part  of  the  United  States  should  also  be 
mentioned.  The  future  changes  in  the  location  and  strength  of  economic 
core  areas  which  can  be  envisaged  as  the  result  of  the  St.  Lawrence  Sea- 
way construction  may  also  make  themselves  felt  in  the  internal  political 
geography  of  the  United  States  and  its  competing  political  cores.24 

Maritime  routes  are  to  a  certain  degree  flexible.  They  can  be  relocated 

2  3  The  Economist,  August  28,  1954,  pp.  663-4.  See  also  below,  pp.  588,  589. 
24  See  pp.  170,  171  on  the  development  of  a  political  core  area  in  California, 


CORE  AREAS,  CAPITAL  CITIES,  COMMUNICATIONS  167 

at  short  notice.  Submarine  warfare  forced  ships  to  change  their  course 
continuously.  Large  vessels,  with  their  independence  of  weather  condi- 
tions and  greater  capacity  for  provisions,  can  afford  direct  travel  without 
use  of  ports-of-call.  On  the  other  hand,  they  are  restricted  to  fewer  har- 
bors. Nor  can  the  largest  ocean  liners  use  the  great  inter-oceanic  canals. 
Venice,  once  a  political  and  economic  center  of  a  far-flung  organization,  is 
unable  to  serve  modern  shipping  because  of  its  shallow  lagoon.  No  large 
seagoing  vessels  are  able  to  sail  up  the  Potomac.  But  this  development  has 
not  affected  the  role  of  Washington  as  a  political  core. 

AIR  COMMUNICATIONS 

Air  communications  have  resulted  in  significant  shifts,  though  none  to 
the  present  moment  have  affected  the  standing  of  political  cores  and 
hardly  of  secondary  political  units.  Alaska  and  Hawaii  have  been  brought 
in  closer  contact  with  the  continental  United  States,  although,  at  the  writ- 
ing of  these  lines,  statehood  has  not  yet  been  granted  to  either  of  them. 

SIGNIFICANCE  OF  RAILROAD  SYSTEMS 

Least  flexible  are  land  communications.  It  is  for  this  reason  that  certain 
roads  and  railroads  have  acquired  great  political  significance.  The  Soviet 
—formerly  Russian— empire  in  Asia  would  be  impossible  in  its  present 
form  without  its  strategic  railroads  (cf.  Fig.  15-2,  p.  478).  The  Trans- 
Siberian  railroad  linked  the  Far  East  to  the  distant  core;  it  initiated  the 
Russification  of  wide  areas;  it  enabled  the  penetration  of  Manchuria  and 
paved  the  way  for  influence  in  China.  The  Turkestan  railroad  enabled, 
accompanied,  and  secured  the  Russian  domination  of  Central  Asia.  A  spur 
from  this  railroad  into  the  oasis  of  Merw  alarmed  the  British  rulers  of 
India.  The  Turksib  railroad,  connecting  the  Turkestan  and  Trans-Siberian 
railroads  and  paralleling  the  Chinese  boundary,  was  a  powerful  instru- 
ment in  bringing  Russian  economic,  social,  and  political  influence  to 
Sinkiang,  the  most  remote  of  the  provinces  of  China. 

The  dependence  of  Russia,  and  later  of  the  Soviet  Union,  on  supplies 
from  its  western  allies  during  both  World  Wars  led  to  the  construction  of 
the  Murmansk  railroad  in  World  War  I  and  the  Trans-Iranian  railroad  in 
World  War  II.  The  first  of  these  two  lines  acquired  a  critical  importance 
for  Finland  and  caused  the  Soviet  Union  to  insist  on  the  cession  of 
sparsely  inhabited,  climatically  adverse  areas  which  appeared  to  the  So- 
viets in  too-close,  threatening  neighborhood  to  the  railroad.  The  construe- 


168  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

tion  of  the  Trans-Iranian  railroad  threatened  to  destroy  the  shaky  inde- 
pendence of  this  country,  which  was  occupied  by  forces  of  the  allied 
Powers. 

Perhaps  in  no  other  part  of  the  world  have  railroads  played  such  a 
political  role  as  in  the  Near  and  Middle  East.  The  short  railroad  from  the 
Russian  boundary  to  Tabriz  signalized  one  step  in  the  repeated  attempts 
of  Russia  to  win  control  of  Persian  Azerbaijan. 

The  Republic  of  Turkey  (cf.  Fig.  8-19,  p.  284)  for  a  long  time,  was 
hesitant  about  allowing  railroad  construction  by  foreign  syndicates.  Its 
reluctance  was  due  to  the  realization  that  generally  investment  of  foreign 
capital  in  undeveloped  countries  has  resulted  in  making  such  countries 
dependent  upon  the  lending  country.  Investment  in  railroads— or  port 
installations— has  been  in  many  cases  the  main  instrument  by  which  con- 
trol of  an  area  could  be  obtained,  and  the  railroad  lines  were  built  more 
in  the  interest  of  the  lending  than  in  that  of  the  borrowing  country.  In 
pre-World  War  I  Turkey,  the  Trans-Anatolian  and  the  Baghdad  railroads 
were  constructed  to  facilitate  German  expansion  southeastward  to  the 
Persian  Gulf.  British  capital  succeeded  in  building  a  railroad  from  the 
Gulf  to  Baghdad,  bringing  lower  Mesopotamia  under  Anglo-Indian  in- 
fluence and  paving  the  way  for  the  creation  of  post-war  Iraq  as  a  British 
mandate. 

With  the  Hedjaz  railroad,  Turkey  attempted  to  counteract  foreign  in- 
terference in  what  it  considered  its  own  sphere  of  influence.  Sultan  Abdul 
Hamid  II  appealed  to  the  religious  feelings  of  the  Mohammedans  in  order 
to  promote  the  construction  of  a  railroad  which  would  facilitate  the  pil- 
grimage to  the  holy  places  of  Islam.  Thus  he  was  able  to  keep  foreign 
capital  out  and  to  build  a  railroad  which  allowed  him  to  send  troops  to 
Hedjaz  and  on  to  Yemen,  thus  by-passing  the  Suez  Canal.  However,  it  was 
too  late  to  strengthen  the  ties  of  these  remote  areas  with  the  political 
center. 


MEASURES  AIMED  AT  REDUCING  THE  INFLUENCE 
OF  THE  POLITICAL  CORE 

In  discussing  the  relationship  of  the  core  to  its  outlying  parts  we  have 
also  to  consider  constitutional  problems.  In  a  compact  country  of  some 
size  the  political  core  in  some  respects  may  be  compared  with  the  center 
of  gravity  in  a  physical  body.  While  all  parts  of  the  body  have  weight, 
they  exert  pull  upon  other  bodies  through  this  center  of  gravity.  The  de- 
cisive difference  is  that  in  nations  and  countries  the  core  generally  has 


CORE  AREAS,  CAPITAL  CITIES,  COMMUNICATIONS  169 

more  weight  than  any  other  comparable  part  of  the  body  politic.  How- 
ever, in  many  instances  this  is  hardly  reflected  in  the  organization  of  the 
state.  Democratic  parliamentary  countries  allow  the  core  area  as  much 
but  not  more  representation  than  any  other  area  with  a  comparable  popu- 
lation. Nevertheless,  the  impact  of  the  agglomeration  of  people  in  the 
capital,  and  of  a  central  bureaucracy,  exerts  a  special  influence.  Several 
devices  have  been  tried  to  avoid  or  to  reduce  this  influence.  The  French 
moved  their  parliament  to  Versailles  on  different  occasions  to  remove  it 
from  the  influence  of  the  "street  mob."  In  the  United  States  the  creation 
of  a  federal  district  apart  from  the  large  cities  has  fulfilled  its  purpose  for 
a  long  period;  but  more  recently  Washington,  D.  C,  as  the  seat  of  the 
national  power,  has  tended  to  attract  great  numbers  of  people,  institu- 
tions, central  offices  of  unions,  and  so  on.  In  several  of  the  forty-eight  states 
the  same  device  has  been  used.  Annapolis  in  Maryland,  Lansing  in  Michi- 
gan, Springfield  in  Illinois,  Harrisburg  in  Pennsylvania,  and  Sacramento 
in  California  are  cases  in  point.  At  least  in  the  last  two  examples  a  devel- 
opment comparable  to  that  of  Washington,  D.  C,  has  set  in.  The  Ameri- 
can example  has  been  imitated  elsewhere,  in  Canberra,  the  capital  of  the 
Australian  Commonwealth,  in  Toronto  in  Canada,  and  in  Brazil  with  the 
designation  of  a  Federal  District,  though  in  this  country  so  far  nothing 
has  been  done  to  move  the  government. 

In  other  countries  an  attempt  was  made  to  split  the  central  organization 
between  several  cities.  The  Netherlands  has  the  seat  of  the  court  and 
some  central  organs  in  The  Hague,  while  the  parliament  convenes  in  Am- 
sterdam. In  the  Union  of  South  Africa  the  parliament  has  its  seat  in  Cape- 
town, the  government  in  Johannesburg,  and  the  Supreme  Court  in  Pre- 
toria. In  Switzerland  the  seat  of  the  government  rotated  between  Zurich, 
Basel,  and  Lucerne.  Despite  a  long  tradition  this  arrangement  was  finally 
abandoned;  however,  the  distinction  between  the  economic  core  in  and 
around  Zurich  and  Lucerne  and  the  political  core  in  Berne  remained  alive. 

COMPETITIVE  CORE  AREAS  IN  OUTLYING  REGIONS 

For  countries  endowed  with  large-size  territories,  the  opening-up  of 
new  lands  in  the  outer  regions  and  population  growth  often  leads  to  the 
development  of  new  core  areas  that  compete  with  the  older  areas  eco- 
nomically, without  necessarily  growing  into  a  competitive  political  core 
except  in  certain  matters  of  internal  politics.  California,  in  its  position 
within  the  United  States  and  among  the  western  states  of  the  Union,  is  an 
interesting  case  in  point  (Fig.  6-12).  California  has  become  an  important 


170  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 


M. 


Fig.  6-12.  The  West  Coast  Core  Area  of  the  United  States  Centered  on  California. 


economic  core  area  of  the  West  Coast  which  includes,  in  addition  to 
California,  the  two  coastal  states  of  Oregon  and  Washington  and  the  four 
"mountain  states"  of  Idaho,  Utah,  Nevada,  and  Arizona.  With  a  total 
population  of  more  than  eighteen  million,  this  area  has  come  to  represent 
a  clearly  defined  economic  bloc  within  the  economy  of  the  country.  This 
fact  of  course  has  not  led  to  a  weakening  of  the  political  structure  of  the 
Union  but  has  brought  about  a  strengthening  of  the  specific  political  in- 
terests and  viewpoints  of  this  area  in  national  politics,  as  for  instance  in  the 
question  of  United  States  policy  toward  Asia.  It  is  also  interesting  to  note 
that  the  development  of  an  economic  core  area  within  California,  far  from 
having  found  its  final  center  of  gravity,  is  still  in  a  state  of  fluctuation.  The 
center  is  shifting  from  the  north  to  the  south.  In  1900  only  one-fifth  of 
California's  population  was  to  be  found  in  southern  California;  at  present 
its  share  is  more  than  one-half.  The  congested  area  of  San  Francisco  had 
to  pay  the  price  for  its  geographical  disadvantages  in  the  competition  with 
the  metropolitan  areas  of  Los  Angeles  and  San  Diego,  which  nature  had 
endowed  with  more  ample  "living  space"  and  less  fog— factors  which 
attracted  especially  the  new  aircraft  industries. 

The  growth  of  the  new  core  area  in  California  finds  significant  expres- 
sion in  the  rise  of  its  electoral  votes.  Their  number  in  a  state  is  based  on 
the  state's  representation  in  Congress,  which  again  is  based  on  the  state's 


CORE  AREAS,  CAPITAL  CITIES,  COMMUNICATIONS  171 

relative  gain  or  loss  in  population  during  a  decade.  California  has  pushed 
its  electoral  vote  up  farther  and  faster  than  any  other  State  in  the  Union. 
After  the  1940  census  it  boosted  the  figure  from  twenty-two  to  twenty-five. 
After  the  1950  census,  California  gathered  in  seven  more— half  of  the  four- 
teen-vote  increase  registered  by  all  the  states.  The  election  of  Richard 
M.  Nixon  to  the  office  of  Vice  President  in  the  Eisenhower  Administration 
underscored  the  importance  of  the  California  secondary  core  area  in  the 
internal  political  geography  of  the  United  States. 


CHECKS  AND  BALANCES  IN  FEDERAL  STATES 

Another  device  by  which  the  influence  of  the  core  area  can  be  balanced 
consists  of  giving  to  less  populous  areas  a  stronger  representation  in  the 
parliament  and  government.  This  is  done  especially  in  federal  states.  In 
the  United  States,  Canada,  Australia,  and  in  Europe  in  Switzerland,  each 
of  the  component  federal  states  has  legal  representation  in  one  chamber, 
thus  giving  more  weight  to  thinly  settled  rural  states.  In  some  of  the  forty- 
eight  states  of  the  United  States  the  "unit  system"  accomplishes  a  similar 
end.  The  frequent  victory,  in  Georgia,  of  a  numerical  minority  of  conserv- 
ative rural  voters  over  a  progressive  city  population  has  had  repercussions 
for  the  entire  United  States. 


THE  POLITICAL  CORE  IN  TOTALITARIAN  COUNTRIES 

The  less  democratic  a  country  is,  the  more  pronounced  is  the  impact  of 
the  political  core.  In  absolute  monarchies  or  in  dictatorships  the  core 
literally  rules  over  the  other  parts.  Although  the  Nazi  party  in  Germany 
or  the  Fascist  movement  in  Italy  originated  outside  the  political  core  and 
the  capital,  the  victory  of  totalitarianism  brought  about  the  concentration 
of  power  in  Berlin  as  well  as  in  Rome,  where  the  "march  on  Rome"  cli- 
maxed the  Fascist  victory.  In  other  countries  also  the  final  success  of 
revolution  has  been  marked  by  the  fall  of  the  capital.  This  is  true  of  almost 
all  the  numerous  Latin  American  revolutions,  and  also  of  the  pattern  of 
revolutions  in  Europe.  The  more  than  two  years  of  civil  war  in  Spain 
ended  with  the  conquest  of  Madrid,  and  the  Bolshevik  regime  came  into 
the  saddle  with  the  conquest  of  Leningrad  and  Moscow.  The  years  of 
civil  war  which  followed  did  not  change  the  outcome.  Neither  the  Ukrain- 
ian breadbasket  nor  the  vital  Donets  industrial  and  mining  area  ever 
competed  with  Moscow  as  fountainheads  of  the  central  political  power. 


172  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

COLONIALISM  AND  CORE  AREAS 

As  mentioned  before,  in  colonial  empires  the  metropolitan  area  as  a 
whole  has  to  be  regarded  as  the  political  core.  It  has  been  noted  by  several 
authors  that  colonial  dependencies  are  not  necessarily  located  in  other 
continents.  The  Amazonian  forests  and  their  little-developed  tribes  are 
typical  colonial  areas  for  Brazil,  Bolivia,  Peru,  and  Colombia.  So  are  the 
cold  areas  of  Patagonia  and  Tierra  del  Fuego  for  Argentina  and  Chile,  the 
Tundra  regions  for  Canada,  Lapland  for  Norway  and  Sweden.  Chinese 
Turkestan  (Sinkiang)  was  a  colonial  overland  possession  of  China.  Con- 
stitutional or  legal  definitions  do  not  always  reflect  the  actual  conditions 
prevailing  in  a  dependent  area  in  relation  to  the  main  body.  In  some  cases 
such  areas  are  treated  like  the  usual  administrative  divisions.  In  other 
cases  they  are  administered  as  "territories."  That  is  the  way  in  which  the 
United  States  administers  the  undeveloped  parts  of  Alaska  together  with 
its  civilized  fringe. 

None  of  these  areas  is  officially  recognized  as  a  colony.  The  term 
"colony"  has  become  unfashionable,  and  designations  such  as  Overseas 
France  or  Overseas  Portugal  have  replaced  it.  For  the  political  geographer 
the  varying  terminology  is  more  confusing  than  helpful.  However,  there 
is  a  great  variety  in  the  degree  of  dependency.  The  Dominions  are  only 
in  a  very  loose  connection  with  the  British  core.  India  has  led  the  way 
toward  a  still  looser  connection,  abrogating  the  symbolic  bond  of  the 
common  crown  and  declaring  itself  a  republic.  Ireland  and  Burma  actu- 
ally left  the  Commonwealth. 

The  constitution  of  the  Soviet  Union  includes  an  article  which  grants 
to  the  full-fledged  Soviet  republics  the  right  to  secede.  History  has  yet  to 
prove  if  this  "right"  exists  on  paper  only.  What  has  become  a  reality  in 
the  British  Commonwealth,  has  so  far  remained  an  empty  promise  in  the 
Soviet  Union. 

The  Soviet  Union  has  established  a  whole  hierarchy  of  dependencies 
from  the  national  okrug  through  the  national  oblast  and  the  autonomous 
soviet  republic  to  the  sixteen  constituent  soviet  republics.  It  allows  the 
satellite  people's  republics  to  be  designated  as  independent  states,  al- 
though in  fact  they  are  less  free  than  many  parts  of  the  British  Common- 
wealth, especially  the  Dominions. 


CORE  AREAS,  CAPITAL  CITIES,  COMMUNICATIONS  173 

RELATIONS  BETWEEN  DEPENDENCIES  AND  CORE  AREAS 

It  is  very  difficult  to  bring  the  dependencies  of  Great  Britain  under  a 
comprehensive  system.  Almost  every  area  is  somewhat  differently  placed 
from  all  others.  There  are  crown  colonies,  administered  by  London- 
appointed  officials,  and  naval  bases  such  as  Gibraltar  under  strict  military 
rule.  In  a  crown  colony  there  may  be  an  advisory  body,  wholly  or  par- 
tially elected,  and  elected  by  white  settlers  only  or  by  natives.  There  are 
different  types  of  self-governing  colonies,  protectorates  where  native 
rulers  and  native  administration  govern,  guided  by  British  advisers.  Some 
dependent  areas  are  not  dependent  on  London,  but  on  one  or  the  other 
of  the  Dominions. 

Although  the  colonial  structure  of  other  powers— French,  Belgian, 
Portuguese,  or  Dutch— is  much  simpler,  they  all  represent  an  attempt  to 
organize  large  areas,  scattered  over  at  least  two  continents,  not  because 
they  form  a  natural  geographic  physical  unit,  but  from  a  core  which 
dominates  by  political  means.  Whatever  the  economic  motives  for  acqui- 
sition and  retention  of  colonies,  the  political  factor  is  in  the  end  decisive. 

There  is  another  group  of  dependent  areas,  those  territories  designated 
as  Mandates  by  the  League  of  Nations  after  World  War  I,  and  as  Trustee- 
ships by  the  United  Nations.  Theoretically  their  overriding  loyalty  should 
go  to  the  United  Nations.  However,  though  certainly  an  object  of  study 
for  the  political  geographer,  the  United  Nations  are  no  political  body  and 
lack  any  organized  area  of  their  own,  therefore  also  any  core  area.  Actu- 
ally all  the  trust  territories  are  dependent  on  the  core  areas  of  their  ad- 
ministering nations. 


CHAPTER 


7 


Location 


INTERACTION  OF  STABLE  AND  CHANGING  CONDITIONS 
AFFECTING  THE  IMPACT  OF  LOCATION 

For  a  century  the  United  States  was  on  the  periphery  of  the  world;  only 
in  the  last  generation  has  it  moved  to  the  center  of  the  stage  and,  on  a 
world-wide  basis,  has  become  a  core  area.  Similarly  it  is  a  generally 
accepted  notion  that  until  the  discovery  of  America,  the  British  Isles  lay 
on  the  very  edge  of  the  known  world,  but  that  thereafter  they  were  at  the 
world's  center  for  the  next  four  centuries.  In  regard  to  their  relations  with 
the  European  continent  a  British  historian  has  pointed  out  that  "to  invade 
Britain  was  singularly  easy  before  the  Norman  Conquest,  singularly  diffi- 
cult afterwards  .  .  .  safe  behind  the  Channel ...  no  invasion  hostile  to  the 
community  as  a  whole  has  met  with  even  partial  success  owing  to  the 
barrier  of  the  sea.  But .  .  .  ancient  Britain  was  peculiarly  liable  to  invasion 
for  geographic  and  other  reasons."  1 

From  a  geographical  point  of  view  one  should  express  the  same  thought 
slightly  differently:  although  the  location  of  a  place  on  the  earth  is  fixed, 
the  political  value  and  implications  of  this  location  are  continuously 
changing.  It  is  this  interaction  of  stable  and  changing  conditions  which  is 
at  the  basis  of  political  geography.  People  have  been  fascinated  by  the 
apparent  stability  of  the  "well-grounded  earth,"  as  it  was  called  three 
thousand  years  ago  by  Hesiod.  They  are  apt  to  look  at  geographic  loca- 
tions and  their  relations  without  taking  account  of  changes  in  time. 

It  is  the  function  of  the  political  geographer  to  point  out  this  integration 

1  G.  M.  Trevelyan,  History  of  England,  Vol.  1  (Garden  City,  N.  Y.,  1953),  pp.  14  ff. 

174 


LOCATION  175 

of  time  and  space  factors  and  to  be  aware  of  the  time-conditioned  ele- 
ments which  affect  his  findings.  Certain  politico-geographical  statements 
or,  in  the  true  sense  of  the  word,  "views"  have  had  great  poignancy  at  one 
time,  but  were  relevant  for  a  short  period  only.  Others  have  kept  their 
validity  over  long  periods.  Both  types  of  statements  are  of  interest,  but 
should  not  be  confused.  Confused  thinking  on  basic  concepts  of  location 
in  political  geography,  affecting  not  only  the  ordinary  citizens  but  states- 
men and  military  strategists  alike,  is  only  due  to  the  failure  to  distinguish 
properly  between  the  time-bound  validity  of  a  politico-geographical  con- 
cept and  its,  in  many  cases  only  seemingly,  timeless  application.  Such 
misinterpretation  of  spatial  relationships  in  location  can  distort,  and  has 
distorted  the  outlook  of  international  relations  which  forms  the  basis  of 
the  foreign  policy  of  the  great  powers. 

LANDLOCKED  AND  INTERIOR  LOCATION 

One  of  the  most  persistent  concepts  of  political  geography  is  concerned 
with  the  location  of  countries  in  close  contact  with  the  sea  or  far  away 
from  it.  This  is  the  long-range  basis  of  the  Heartland  theory  2  which  must 
be  seen  as  a  special,  period-bound  example  of  the  politico-geographical 
conditions  of  landlocked  or  interior  location  which  have  been  tested  by 
History  time  and  again.  In  antiquity  a  landlocked  Macedonia  remained 
dependent  upon  Athens,  until  Philip,  the  father  of  Alexander  the  Great, 
conquered  the  coastal  cities.  It  is  generally  believed  that  landlocked  loca- 
tions are  a  serious  disadvantage  to  the  state  concerned.  This  is  correct  in 
many  respects;  however,  in  a  strictly  strategic  sense  a  landlocked  position 
may  provide  a  nation  engaged  in  war  with  the  advantage  of  the  "inner 
line."  Given  a  system  of  good  communications,  a  well-developed  system 
of  intelligence,  and  good  armies  under  able  leadership,  a  country  can  use 
its  interior  location  to  shift  troops  from  one  front  to  another  and  thus  win 
victories  by  local  superiority.  Frederick  of  Prussia,  Napoleon,  and  also  the 
Bolsheviks  during  the  Civil  War  of  the  Bevolution  made  the  best  use  of 
location  factors  of  interior  location  which,  except  for  the  advantages  they 
offered  in  war  strategy,  were  highly  disadvantageous. 

The  disadvantages  of  interior  location  are  manifold,  particularly  in  that 
a  landlocked  country  is  deprived  of  the  opportunity  to  have  direct  contact 
with  any  country  except  those  with  which  it  has  common  boundaries.  This 
is  still  true,  although  it  must  be  realized  that  the  great  advantages  which 

2  For  a  discussion  of  the  relationship  of  Heartland  expansion  to  marginal  lands  and 
narrow  waterways,  see  pp.  113  ff. 


176  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

the  seafaring  peoples  enjoyed  over  those  of  the  interior  lands  before  the 
full  establishment  of  mechanical  transport  on  land  and  in  the  air  are  no 
longer  as  distinctive  as  was  the  case  only  fifty  years  ago.  But  even  though 
the  progress  of  technology  has  aided  greatly  in  the  utilization  of  diversi- 
fied land  areas  and  in  establishing  continuity  and  compactness  of  the 
territory,  the  fact  has  not  been  altered  that  every  country  remains  depend- 
ent on  one  or  all  of  its  neighbors.  Modern  industrialization  and  modern 
commerce  with  their  dependence  on  a  great  variety  of  raw  materials  have 
rather  sharpened  this  relation. 

BOUNDARIES  AND  NEIGHBORS 

The  question  has  been  raised  as  to  whether  it  is  more  favorable  for  a 
country  to  border  with  many  or  with  few  other  countries.  Experience  has 
shown  that  the  fact  that  the  United  States  has  only  two  neighbors  has 
simplified  many  problems.  Germany,  in  contrast,  has  suffered  from  the 
fact  that  it  has  had  to  deal  with  a  great  number  of  neighbors.  It  requires 
a  very  skillful  handling  of  foreign  affairs  to  maintain  tolerable  relations 
with  neighboring  countries  of  different,  often  contradictory  interests.  The 
situation  is  aggravated  by  the  fact  that  a  coalition  of  several  of  these 
neighbor  countries  is  always  a  possibility.  Bismarck,  himself  a  master  in 
the  diplomatic  game  of  coalitions,  confessed  that  during  his  chancellor- 
ship he  was  continuously  plagued  by  the  "nightmare  of  coalitions."  Hitler 
thought  himself  strong  enough  to  neglect  this  possibility  and  led  a  poten- 
tially victorious  Germany  into  catastrophe. 

For  a  landlocked  state,  to  have  only  very  few  neighbors  may  equally  be 
a  great  disadvantage.  The  extreme  case  of  a  country  with  only  one  neigh- 
bor, which  would  mean  that  it  is  completely  surrounded,  is  seldom  found 
in  recent  history.  The  Boer  states  offer  as  close  an  example  as  possible. 
Save  for  a  short  boundary  in  remote  terrain  with  an  undeveloped  Portu- 
guese colony,  the  two  Boer  states,  Transvaal  and  the  Orange  Free  State, 
were  at  one  time  completely  surrounded  by  British  territory  (Fig.  7-1). 
In  the  ensuing  struggle  the  Boers  succumbed.  However,  in  this  struggle 
even  the  remote  connection  with  Portuguese  Laurenco  Marques  was  of 
great  value. 

BUFFER  LOCATION 

To  be  placed  between  only  two  states  is  a  location  which  seriously 
affects  the  power  position  of  any  state  but  especially  of  a  weak  one.  At 
best  it  becomes  a  buffer  state.  Its  continued  existence  depends  on  the 


LOCATION 


177 


Fig.  7-1.  The  Boer  States  in  Relation  to  British  and  Portuguese  Territories. 


agreement  between  the  two  neighbor  states  or  at  least  on  stable  relations 
between  them.  Persia,  Afghanistan,  or  Siam  in  the  first  years  of  the  twen- 
tieth century  are  examples.  All  three  states  owed  their  continuing  inde- 
pendence not  so  much  to  internal  strength,  but  to  treaties  between  Britain 
and  Russia,  and  Britain  and  France,  based  on  the  desire  to  keep  the  other 
power  out  of  the  respective  area  and  still  to  maintain  good  relations  with 
this  power  (Fig.  7-2).  A  similar  agreement,  in  this  case  between  three 
powers— Britain,  France,  and  Italy— kept  the  independence  of  Ethiopia 
intact  for  some  time  ( Fig.  7-3 ) .  When  France  and  Britain  were  no  longer 
ready  or  able  to  wage  war  for  Ethiopian  independence,  and  when  Italy 
was  ready  to  risk  friendly  relations  with  these  powers,  Ethiopia  became  a 
victim  of  Italian  expansion  in  1935.  If  buffer  countries  become  strong 
enough  to  be  able  to  defend  their  independence  themselves  with  some 


178 


THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 


Fig.  7-2.  The  Buffer  States  of  Iran  ( Persia ) ,  Afghanistan,  and  Thailand  ( Siam ) 

before  the  Partition  of  India. 


chance  of  success,  they  cease  to  be  buffers.  Switzerland,  favored  by  its 
natural  and  easily  defensible  environment  in  the  midst  of  high  mountains, 
with  its  people  cherishing  the  tradition  of  liberty,  with  its  economy  geared 
to  war-preparedness,  can  hardly  be  called  a  buffer  state.  However,  its 
favorable  position  is  also  due  to  the  fact  that  it  has  four  competing  neigh- 
bors. When  Germany  annexed  one  of  these  neighbors,  Austria,  in  1938, 
and  occupied  the  territory  of  the  second,  France,  in  1940,  Switzerland  had 
to  make  some  concessions  which  might  have  compromised  its  neutrality; 
but  it  was  forced  to  these  concessions  in  order  to  preserve  the  essence  of 
its  neutrality  and  independence. 

A  country  becomes  a  buffer  and  maintains  this  quality  not  by  its  loca- 
tion alone.  An  additional  and  intangible  requirement  is  the  will  to  remain 
independent  despite  powerful  neighbors.  Finland,  between  East  and 
West,  is  a  splendid  example  of  such  a  buffer  state  determination.  In  con- 
trast, the  chain  of  states  from  Poland  to  Bulgaria  were  consolidated  by 
the  U.S.S.R.  in  a  bloc  organization,  and  virtually  ceased  to  be  independ- 
ent states  when  a  relatively  large  sector  of  their  population,  after  1945, 
was  blinded  by  the  might  of  the  Soviet  Union  and  did  not  regard  national 
independence  a  supreme  value.  They  exchanged  their  status  as  buffer 
states,  which  they  had  maintained  in  the  period  between  the  two  World 
Wars,  for  that  of  satellites. 

Not  all  buffer  states  are  landlocked;  neither  Iran,  nor  Thailand,  Finland, 
or  before  their  inclusion  in  the  Soviet  bloc  Poland,  Rumania,  or  Bulgaria 
can  be  called  landlocked  in  the  strict  sense  of  the  word.  However,  the 
coasts  of  most  of  these  states  are  on  an  inland  sea,  the  exit  of  which  to  the 
open  ocean  is  practically  closed.  Iran's  coast  is  very  remote  from  the  set- 
tled centers  of  the  country,  separated  from  them  by  high  mountains  and 


LOCATION 


179 


Fig.  7-3.  The  Buffer  State  of  Ethiopia  before  1935. 


hot  deserts.  If  it  were  not  for  the  very  short  coastal  stretch  near  the  mouth 
of  the  Shatt  el  Arab,  Iran  despite  its  many  hundred  miles  of  seacoast 
would  be  a  maritime  state  only  in  name. 

A  peculiar  situation  develops  if  a  country  is  penned  in  between  a  large 
neighbor  country  and  the  anecumene.  In  this  context  the  ocean  can  not 
be  regarded  as  part  of  the  anecumene  as  the  navies  of  all  countries  are 
free  to  approach  all  its  coasts.  Thus  the  above  description  could  with  slight 
qualification  apply  to  Portugal  which,  in  the  past,  in  a  typical  buffer-state 
position  between  the  larger  neighbor  Spain,  and  a  British  dominated  sea, 
and  in  the  true  spirit  of  independence,  retained  its  freedom  against  re- 
peated onslaught.  Like  the  ocean  much  earlier,  now  deserts  and  the  Arctic 
are  beginning  to  loose  their  true  character  as  anecumene.  It  is  doubtful 
whether  Greenland  and  Iceland,  with  their  back  to  the  Arctic,  and  Lybia, 
with  its  back  to  the  Sahara,  will  retain  this  character  much  longer.  Perhaps 
Oman  and  Hadramaut  in  Southern  Arabia  are  the  last  perfect  examples. 
In  the  not  too  distant  past  such  countries  as  England,  Japan,  or  the  Philip- 
pine Islands  were  in  this  position.  And  Ireland,  Australia,  and  New  Zea- 
land are  accommodating  themselves  to  new  relationships  under  our  very 
eyes. 


180 


THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 


•^'  R      A      Z       I       L 


\     ..-6  y 

Rio  Branco  ,-S 

R     .     °  rr 


PERU 


~v 


BOLIVIA 


Cochabamba 


"N..-.V  • 


PA   R  A  G  U  A  ¥ 


\ 


ARGENT1  NA 


«...-<, 


Fig.  7-4.  Boundary  Conflicts  in  South  America:  the  Acre  dispute;  Bolivia's 

lost  access  to  the  sea. 


BACKDOOR"  AREAS 


The  classical  example  of  a  basically  landlocked  country  is  Russia  and 
its  successor  the  U.S.S.R.  Its  Arctic  coast  and  especially  its  harbors  of 
Murmansk  and  Archangelsk  have  often  been  called  Russia's  backdoor. 
That  designation  does  not  refer  as  much  to  the  difficult  access  from  the 
sea,  as  to  their  remote  distance  from  the  core  areas  of  the  U.S.S.R.,  indeed 
from  any  economically  significant  part  of  the  country.  Large,  almost  unin- 
habited, and  inhospitable  areas  of  virgin,  swampy  forest,  the  taiga,  and 
moss-covered  wind-swept  cold  steppe,  the  tundra,  separate  the  few  coastal 
settlements  and  a  few  mining  districts  from  the  rest  of  the  country. 


LOCATION 


181 


*-n 


i 


PERU 


BOLIVIA    5 , 


Cochabamba 


Santa  Cruz;^**_^    } 

__:.  ^"*£:Corumba 

/— "    NT 


ARGENTINA 

i 


Fig.  7-5.  Bolivia  to  the  Sea  via  Brazil:   (1)  existing  railroad;   (2)  proposed  railroad; 

( 3 )  highway  link. 

In  South  America  every  country  except  Uruguay  has  such  boundaries, 
remote,  difficult  to  reach  through  tropical  forest  or  over  towering  moun- 
tains. Though,  seemingly,  the  exact  location  of  these  boundaries  could  not 
be  of  great  value  to  these  countries,  their  national  pride  and  the  hope  of 
finding  hidden  natural  resources  hindered  them  from  compromise.  The 
remoteness  of  these  boundaries  also  prevented  their  exact  delimitation  and 
demarcation  and  thus  caused  many  conflicts.  Brazil,  Bolivia,  and  Peru 
quarreled  over  the  Acre  territory  when  wild  rubber  rendered  this  hitherto 
unknown  area  a  country  of  great  potential  value  ( Fig.  7-4 ) .  Peru,  Colom- 
bia, and  Ecuador  for  similar  reasons  competed  for  the  Oriente,  an  area 
which  in  addition  gives  access  to  the  Amazon.  Bolivia  and  Paraguay  went 
to  war  over  the  Chaco.  Bolivia,  for  economic  reasons,  and  reasons  of  pres- 
tige, wanted  access  to  the  Rio  Parana.  This  would  be  a  typical  inconven- 
ient backdoor  through  steaming,  practically  uninhabited  tropical  forests 
to  an  undeveloped  river  port  far  inland  and  to  an  outlet  to  the  sea  on  the 
other  side  of  the  continent.  It  would  still  be  a  valuable  gate  to  the  outer 
world,  as  the  main  entrance  from  the  Pacific  Ocean  is  firmly  in  the  hands 
of  Peru  and  Chile.  The  corridor  to  the  ports  of  Tacna  and  Arica,  once 
owned  by  Bolivia,  was  lost  in  the  Pacific  War  of  1884  and  seems  beyond 
hope  of  recovery  ( Fig.  7-4 ) .  In  1955,  Bolivia  at  last  took  a  step  in  easing 
its  landlocked  position,  when  a  highway-railroad  link  between  Brazil  and 
Bolivia  was  completed  (Fig.  7-5). 

Even  in  densely  populated  European  states  such  as  Portugal,  the  Neth- 


182  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

erlands,  Norway,  Sweden,  and  Finland,  all  of  which  front  the  sea,  the 
backdoor  areas  are  in  thinly  inhabited  inland  areas.  Much  less  frequent 
is  the  country  facing  inland  with  its  coast  containing  the  backdoor.  Such 
is  Yugoslavia.  Though  the  interests  of  its  coastal  population  are  definitely 
bound  up  with  fishing  and  shipping,  the  main  bulk  of  the  country  and  its 
population  has  little  contact  with  this  coastal  area.  Rugged,  karstic  moun- 
tains are  a  powerful  barrier  to  settlement  and  communications. 

Neither  Chile  nor  Peru  have  significant  interests  on  or  across  the  sea. 
But  Chile  is,  nonetheless,  a  coastal  country,  looking  toward  the  sea,  while 
for  Peru  the  interior  is  as  important  as  the  coast.  In  Europe,  Belgium's 
land  boundaries  are  much  more  important  than  its  short  coast.  The  one 
great  Belgian  harbor,  Antwerp,  is  accessible  only  through  the  Scheldt 
river,  the  mouth  of  which  Belgium  shares  with  the  Netherlands. 

THE  URGE  TO  THE  SEA 

It  is  understandable  that  interior  states  try  to  reach  the  open  sea.  His- 
tory is  full  of  conflicts  between  interior  states  and  coastal  powers  blocking 
their  road  to  the  sea.  Ethiopia  has  been  cut  off  from  the  sea  by  Italian, 
British,  and  French  colonies  since  the  second  half  of  the  nineteenth  cen- 
tury (cf.  Fig.  7-3,  p.  179).  Only  their  rivalry  kept  it  from  losing  its  political 
independence,  while  economically  its  underdeveloped  condition  made  it 
less  vulnerable  to  economic  pressure.  Thus  it  faced  the  dilemma  of 
whether  to  remain  undeveloped  and  fall  prey  for  this  very  reason  to  more 
highly  developed  countries  sooner  or  later,  or  to  slide  into  economic  de- 
pendency in  the  course  of  its  own  progress.  Many  factors  contributed  to 
Ethiopia's  involvement  in  the  ideological  world  conflict,  to  its  conquest 
by  Italy,  and  finally  to  its  liberation.  Together  with  its  freedom,  Ethiopia 
won  the  coveted  exit  to  the  sea  (cf.  Fig.  7-3,  p.  179). 

A  much  older  and  still  lasting  struggle  for  free  access  to  the  sea  is  that 
of  Russia  and,  since  1917,  the  Soviet  Union.3  Interior  location  is,  in  Russia, 
usually  assumed  under  the  implied  or  acknowledged  supposition  that  the 
ice-barred  Arctic  coast  does  not  have  any  practical  value.  Even  today,  this 
assumption  can  be  accepted  as  correct  in  a  general  way  despite  the  prog- 
ress which  the  Soviet  Union  and  Canada  have  made  in  the  utilization  of 
the  Arctic  Sea  and  coast  by  means  of  icebreakers,  aviation,  and  weather 
stations.  This  utilization  has  been  favored  by  recent  climatic  changes.  In 
the  last  half  century  the  Arctic  Ocean  has  become  warmer  and  the  ice 

3  R.  J.  Kerner,  Russia's  Urge  to  the  Sea  (Berkeley,  Calif.,  1942),  and  his  chapter 
on  "The  Soviet  Union  as  a  Sea  Power,"  in  H.  W.  Weigert,  V.  Stefansson,  and  R.  E. 
Harrison,  eds.,  New  Compass  of  the  World  (New  York,  1949),  pp.  104-123. 


LOCATION  183 

border  has  receded,  making  navigation  and  living  conditions  possible  in 
some  formerly  closed  areas.  Whether  this  climatic  amelioration  will  re- 
main a  permanent  feature  we  do  not  know.  In  any  event,  certain  technical 
advances,  such  as  the  use  of  radio,  radar,  and  aviation  for  ice  reconnais- 
sance, the  use  of  strong  icebreakers,  and  so  on,  will  further  contribute  to 
the  utilization  of  the  Arctic.  In  terms  of  strategy  both  the  U.S.S.R.  and 
Canada  are  interested  in  strengthening  their  control  of  the  Arctic  coast 
(cf.  Fig.  8-11,  p.  252).  Whether  this  effort  will  bear  economical  fruit  in 
time  of  peace  remains  to  be  seen,  despite  the  spread  of  settlement  north, 
which  goes  forward  on  a  small  scale  and  at  great  cost.4  We  shall  discuss 
developments  in  the  Arctic  "Mediterranean"  later  in  greater  detail.5 

Located  originally  in  a  secluded  forest  area  of  Eastern  Europe,  the  state 
of  the  princes  of  Moscow  developed  near  the  source  of  several  rivers, 
flowing  to  different  seas.  Much  of  Russia's  history  can  be  understood  if  we 
see  it  as  a  continuous  struggle,  kindled  time  and  again  by  the  urge  to  the 
sea.  In  earliest  times  this  urge  was  limited  to  attempts  to  utilize  the  navi- 
gable rivers.  The  first  time  Russia  reached  the  sea  it  was  at  the  Arctic 
Ocean  and  this  proved  to  be  of  very  limited  value,  both  because  of  the 
inhospitable  and  remote  nature  of  the  sea,  and  of  the  long  and  difficult 
access  to  the  coast  from  the  interior.  Only  since  World  War  I  has  Mur- 
mansk been  connected  by  a  railroad  with  the  interior.  Gradually,  several 
seas  were  reached:  in  the  southeast,  in  1557,  the  Caspian  Sea  at  Astrakhan; 
in  the  east,  in  1635,  the  Sea  of  Okhotsk;  in  the  west,  about  1700,  the  Baltic 
Sea  at  St.  Petersburg  (today  Leningrad);  in  the  south,  in  1713,  the  Sea 
of  Azov  and  through  it,  in  1783,  the  Black  Sea.  All  these  exits  proved  un- 
satisfactory. Either  they  led  into  enclosed  seas,  such  as  the  Baltic  and  the 
Black  Sea,  or  over  immense,  almost  uninhabited  stretches,  as  to  the  Pacific 
Ocean.  Although  the  frontages  at  the  sea  have  expanded,  they  have  re- 
mained basically  unsatisfactory.  The  Soviet  Union,  as  the  heir  of  Russia, 
has  established  itself  as  the  paramount,  hardly  challenged  power  in  the 
Baltic,  Black,  and  Caspian  Seas,  but  still  the  exits  from  the  first  two  seas 
are  in  foreign  hands,6  and  the  Caspian  Sea  has  no  outlet.  Therefore  the 
pressure  is  still  mounting,  also  and  significantly  in  directions  where  not 

4  The  fact  that  the  North  American  nations  lag  behind  the  U.S.S.R.  in  Arctic  re- 
search and  development  should  not  detract  from  their  achievements  in  recent  years. 
To  mention  one  significant  development,  two  American  and  one  Canadian  icebreakers 
navigated  in  the  fall  of  1954  the  Northwest  Passage  leading  from  the  Atlantic  Ocean 
to  the  Beaufort  Sea,  thus  laying  the  groundwork  for  the  development  of  the  mineral 
and  biological  resources  in  the  Canadian  North,  of  which  the  vast  iron  ore  deposits  in 
northern  Labrador  are  most  important. 

5  See  pp.  246  ff. 

6  See  pp.  242  ff . 


184  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

even  a  limited  success  has  been  achieved  so  far,  as  across  Iran  to  the  Indian 
Ocean.  The  recurrent  pressure  on  Turkey  to  deliver  the  Straits  into  Soviet 
hands  and  the  pressure  on  the  Scandinavian  States  and  Denmark  to  open 
free  access  to  the  Atlantic  cannot  be  explained  by  Communist  ideology  or 
temporary  constellations  (cf.  Fig.  8-7,  p.  238);  they  are  inherent  in  the 
disabilities  of  a  landlocked  position.  A  further  means  to  combat  the  dis- 
advantages due  to  landlocked  position  is  the  canal  system  of  the  U.S.S.R. 
which  permits  small  navy  vessels  to  go  from  the  Arctic  Ocean  to  the  Baltic 
Sea,  and  from  the  Baltic  Sea  to  the  Black  Sea. 

In  general  each  coastal  state  has  potential  contact  with  all  other  coastal 
states  of  the  globe,  that  is,  with  more  than  90  per  cent  of  all  independent 
states.  In  situations  where  it  appeared  impossible  to  establish  a  route  to 
the  sea  over  a  country's  own  territory,  occasionally  the  substitute  of  a  free 
harbor  was  chosen,  sometimes  with  shipping  privileges  secured  on  a  river. 
Czechoslovakia  owned  and  still  owns  free  harbors  in  Hamburg  and 
Szescszin  (the  former  Stettin),  Austria  in  Trieste,  and  Yugoslavia  poten- 
tially in  Salonica,  a  commentary  on  the  above-mentioned  inaccessibility 
and  remoteness  of  her  own  coast  ( see  pp.  33,  198  ff . ) .  But  only  Czecho- 
slovakia has  the  right  to  dispatch  ships  or  barges  on  an  internationalized 
river  to  these  ports.  Though  few  rivers  have  been  put  under  an  inter- 
national regime  to  secure  access  to  the  sea  from  interior  states,  these  few 
are  of  importance,  and  among  them,  of  primary  importance,  the  Rhine. 
Switzerland  has  a  growing  Rhine  merchant  fleet,  based  on  Basel,  and  even 
a  few  seagoing  vessels.  Both  France  and  Germany  built  canals  from  the 
Rhine  through  their  own  territory  to  national  harbors;  nevertheless,  for 
both  countries  the  Rhine  traffic  on  the  internationalized  river  to  its  mouth 
in  Dutch  territory  has  always  remained  of  greater  interest  than  the  canal 
traffic  to  the  Rhone  and  Marne  or  the  Ems  and  the  port  of  Emden. 

The  Danube  has  always  played  a  lesser  role.  Several  reasons  account 
for  this,  among  them  the  geography  of  the  rapids  which  alternate  with 
sections  of  shallows  and  sandbars,  its  mouth  in  the  closed-in  Black  Sea, 
and  the  little-advanced  economic  conditions  of  much  of  its  drainage  basin. 
Political  causes  have  contributed  to  this  stagnant  condition.  Until  1914, 
and  to  a  lesser  degree  from  1919  to  1938,  an  international  organization 
controlled  the  Danube.  The  post-1945  conditions  for  a  while  cut  the 
river  in  two  parts.  Gradually  navigation  along  the  whole  river  has  been 
resumed,  first  by  Yugoslav  shipping.  Lately  Austrian  and  German  ships 
were  admitted  in  parts  of  the  Soviet  area,  but  the  eastern  Danubian  coun- 
tries form  a  separate  international  organization  completely  dominated  by 
the  Soviet  Union. 


LOCATION  185 

When  the  Congo  State  (Fig.  7-6)  was  founded,  Britain  tried  to  hinder 
the  creation  of  this  new  political  body  by  inducing  Portugal  to  reassert 
century-old  claims  to  the  whole  West  African  coast  from  a  point  north  of 
the  mouth  of  the  Congo.  In  1785,  the  Portuguese  had  established  a  fort 
at  Cabinda,  about  thirty  miles  north  of  the  mouth  of  the  Congo.  The 
French  explorer  de  Brazza  reached  the  Congo  near  what  is  today  Brazza- 
ville and  claimed  the  northern  bank  of  the  lower  Congo  for  France. 
Finally  at  the  Congo  Conference  in  Berlin,  1884  to  1885,  an  agreement  was 
reached  which  left  the  newly-founded  Congo  State,  the  present  Belgian 
Congo,  with  an  outlet  to  the  sea  on  the  northern  bank  of  the  Congo  River, 
conceding  the  southern  bank  and  the  territory  of  Cabinda  to  Portugal, 
and  most  of  the  western  bank  of  the  lower  Congo  farther  inland  to  France. 
This  outlet  proved  to  be  so  unsatisfactory  when  a  railroad  to  the  port  of 
Matadi  was  to  be  constructed,  that  in  1927  Belgium  exchanged  with  Portu- 
gal 1350  square  miles  of  inland  territory  for  only  one  square  mile  near 
Matadi  (cf.  Fig.  5-2,  p.  123). 

As  it  turned  out,  the  southeastern  corner  of  the  Belgian  Congo  became 
the  most  valuable  part  of  the  colony  because  of  its  rich  mineral  resources.7 
Transportation  to  the  coastal  port  of  Matadi  is  very  inconvenient  because 
of  the  necessary  transloading  several  times  between  river  and  rail  and 
because  of  the  long  distance.  Thus,  despite  the  tariff  advantages  which 
this  all-Belgian  line  offers,  the  Portuguese  railroad  through  Angola  and 
to  the  port  of  Benguela  and  the  connection  with  British  Rhodesia  could 
tap  a  large  part  of  the  traffic  going  to  either  distant  South  Africa  or  to  the 
Portuguese  East  African  port  of  Beira. 

In  most  of  these  cases  the  railroad  outlets  were  constructed  with  mutual 
agreement  and  to  the  mutual  advantage  of  the  powers  concerned.  How- 
ever, where  such  arrangements  are  unfeasible,  the  blocked  state  may 
force  an  unwilling  neighbor  by  territorial  annexation  or  by  boundary  re- 
adjustments to  supply  the  railroad  outlet.  The  best  known  example  is  that 
of  the  South  Manchurian  Railroad  and  the  Chinese  Eastern  Railroad  to 
Dairen.  Here  Czarist  Russia  forced  upon  China  an  outlet  to  the  ice-free 
sea,  only  to  lose  it  to  the  stronger  power  of  Japan.8 

The  new  British  dominion  of  Central  Africa,  formed  as  recently  as  1953 
and  including  Northern  Rhodesia,  Southern  Rhodesia,  and  Nyassaland 

7  The  Congo  produced  in  1954  more  than  50  per  cent  of  the  Free  World's  uranium, 
80  per  cent  of  its  cobalt,  70  per  cent  of  its  industrial  diamonds,  8  per  cent  of  its  copper, 
and  8  per  cent  of  its  tin. 

8  R.  B.  Johnson,  "Political  Salients  and  Transportation  Solutions:  as  Typified  by 
Eastern  North  America  and  Manchuria,"  Annals  of  the  American  Association  of  Geog- 
raphers, Vol.  39  (March,  1949),  pp.  71,  72. 


"    ^^^^w^^2. 


o 

Or 

T       6 

HI 

o 

Or 

o 

•0 

o  J 

* 

O 

o 

O  j 

O 

* 

c<) 

O 

o 

O  ' 

O  i 

<\J 

CO 

o 

O  -I 

oL 

oil 

as 

£ 

•- 

0) 

eej 

£ 

<u 

x> 

cs 

bti 

> 

a 

Z 

. , 

i— i 

* 

Bfl 

T5 

.2 

58 

C 
— 

a> 

7^ 

T) 

a 

O 

■— 

„3 

T, 

- 

O 

o 

a 

n 

— 

— 

a 

= 

13 
S 

-r 

Tl 

»r\ 

3 

w— 

C 

m 

M 

U 

3 
— 
— 
O 

3 
— 

en 

- 

3 

O 

C\ 

u 

S 

--. 

3 

CU 

M 

3 

1) 

3 

« 

C/l 

-3 

S 

cd 

V 

c 

V 

- 

£ 

'« 

u 

■— 

.fl 

. — ^ 

CO 

C 

- • 

O 

ca 

— 

a 

ed 

S 

o 

'5 

U 

— 

3 

T5 

o 

« 

4-i 

O 

— 

X 

T^J 

o 

fN 

^— ' 

03 

O 

~ 

^- 

< 

^^ 

« 

Si 

■M 

S 

at 

U 

o 

t^ 

u 

■- 

186 


LOCATION  187 

(cf.  Fig.  23-1,  p.  690)  is  also  a  landlocked  area.  Most  of  the  conventional 
political  maps  do  not  depict  clearly  its  landlocked  quality  as  they  show 
Central  Africa  as  well  as  the  British  Mandate  of  Tanganyika  and  the 
Union  of  South  Africa  in  the  same  color.  The  Union  of  South  Africa  has 
made  major  efforts  to  extend  its  ideology  and  its  economic  system  over 
this  area.  It  is  in  a  position  to  exert  strong  economic  pressure  since  it  is 
the  main  customer  of  the  Central  African  territories  and  because  the  main 
railroad  link  leads  into  the  Union.  Thus  the  railroad  into  Portuguese 
Mozambique  to  Beira  and  even  by  way  of  Katanga  to  Angola  wins  polit- 
ical importance.  The  river-links  to  the  sea,  the  Zambesi  and  its  tributary 
the  Shire— the  latter  the  only  direct  outlet  of  Nyassaland— are  obstructed 
by  cataracts  and  are  without  sufficient  depth  during  the  dry  period. 

How  important  a  river  can  be  as  outlet,  if  it  has  no  obstacles  to  navi- 
gation, is  shown  by  the  Paraguay  and  Plata  rivers.  They  are  for  Bolivia 
potentially  an  important  outlet  to  the  sea,  and  function  as  such  for  Para- 
guay. An  even  more  striking  example  is  the  Amazon.  Although  it  involves 
long  transport  from  a  Peruvian  Pacific  port  by  way  of  the  Panama  Canal, 
Peruvian  shippers  find  this  river  route  a  more  convenient,  cheaper,  and 
faster  way  for  bulk  wares  than  the  difficult  and  tedious  transport  of  wares 
across  the  high  Andes  and  through  the  steaming  forests  to  the  Oriente  of 
Peru  (cf.  Fig.  22-2,  p.  674). 

The  Great  Lakes  are  drained  by  the  St.  Lawrence  River  but  the  barrier 
of  the  Niagara  Falls  has  enabled  other  routes  to  compete  as  shipping  out- 
lets. Through  the  Illinois  River  ships  pass  to  the  Mississippi.  Through 
Georgian  Bay  and  the  Ottawa  River,  and  from  Lake  Erie  through  the 
Mohawk  and  Hudson  rivers,  they  go  to  New  York.  Gradually  canals  and 
railroads  have  replaced  the  ancient  portages.  The  struggle  for  the  St. 
Lawrence  Seaway  (cf.  Fig.  6-11,  p.  166)  is  only  one  phase  in  the  age-old 
struggle  to  direct  the  area  around  the  Great  Lakes  inland  or  outward  to 
the  Sea,  to  use  a  favorable  coastal  position  to  dominate,  or  at  least  to 
exploit  this  area  of  interior  position.  This  struggle  for  the  domination  of 
the  Great  Lakes'  traffic  has  become  quite  complex.  At  one  time  it  was  suf- 
ficient to  occupy  a  coastal  station  like  Manhattan  Island  or  Montreal  to 
assure  control  of  the  access  to  the  Great  Lakes.  Today  a  combination  of 
transportation  improvements  and  economic  inducements  is  necessary  to 
secure  for  any  port  a  share  in  this  profitable  traffic.9 

9  See  also  pp.  165,  166  on  the  role  of  the  St.  Lawrence  Seaway  in  the  develop- 
ment of  economic  core  areas  in  the  United  States. 


188  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

SEA  POWER  POSITIONS  AND  EXPANSION  INLAND 

The  domination  of  large  continental  areas  has  been  attempted  many 
times  by  sea  powers.  In  the  past  the  occupation  of  a  coastal  island  or  of 
a  headland  was  sometimes  sufficient  to  assure  complete  domination  of  the 
hinterland.  Phoenicians,  Greeks,  medieval  Italian  cities,  the  Portuguese, 
Dutch,  French,  and  British  succeeded  each  other  in  this  type  of  locational 
struggle.  Few  relics  of  such  sites  exist  today.  The  British  crown  colony  of 
Hongkong  is  probably  the  most  important.  However,  its  function  has 
changed.  It  no  longer  dominates  China  by  its  trade,  but  has  become  the 
main  point  of  contact  between  China  and  the  West.  At  one  time  Port 
Arthur  in  Russian  hands  assumed  a  similar  position  in  regard  to  Man- 
churia. Portuguese  Macao,  the  Portuguese  colonies  on  the  Indian  coast, 
and  international  Tangier  in  Morocco  have  become  fossils  without  impor- 
tant functions. 

Other  somewhat  similar  places,  especially  in  Africa,  became  the  starting 
points  for  expansion  inland.  Mombasa  in  Kenya  and  Bathurst  in  Gambia 
have  retained  their  protected  location  on  an  island  close  to  the  coast,  re- 
sembling the  location  of  Manhattan  Island.  So  did  Lagos  in  Nigeria  on  an 
island  in  the  lagoons,  and  Dakar  in  French  West  Africa  at  the  tip  of  a 
peninsula.  Their  present  functions,  however,  are  no  longer  the  same  as  in 
the  past.  These  places  are  no  longer  the  trading  posts  of  a  foreign  power, 
assuring  an  economic  stranglehold  on  the  hinterland.  With  the  strengthen- 
ing and  political  consolidation  of  the  hinterland  these  coastal  sites  have 
become  the  trade  outlets  of  what  in  most  cases  has  become  a  politically 
integrated  area.  Bombay  and  Calcutta  in  India  also  come  to  mind.  Certain 
of  these  coastal  towns  have  become  the  capitals  of  their  territories.  More 
indicative  of  the  real  situation  are  the  capitals  that  have  been  transferred 
to  inland  cities,  as  to  Nairobi  from  Mombasa  or  to  New  Delhi  from  Cal- 
cutta, stressing  thereby  the  politically  subordinated  position  of  the  harbor 
town. 

A  similar  process,  though  under  slightly  different  conditions,  took  place 
in  the  United  States  towards  the  end  of  the  colonial  period.  As  the  original 
colonies  expanded,  capitals  also  were  moved  inland  from  the  first  coastal 
settlements,  from  New  York  to  Albany,  from  Philadelphia  to  Harrisburg, 
from  Jamestown  to  Richmond,  from  Charlestown  to  Columbia,  and  from 
Savannah  to  Atlanta.  Of  course,  these  cities  were  from  the  beginning  the 
centers  of  European  agrarian  settlement  as  well  as  trading  posts  for  the 
overseas  trade.  Dutch  New  Amsterdam,  today's  New  York,  bears  the 
closest  resemblance  to  the  African  examples. 


LOCATION  189 

LOCATION  AND  NATIONAL  SECURITY 

A  related  modern  problem  concerns  the  advisability  of  removing  indus- 
trial and  political  centers  from  frontier  zones  for  security  reasons.  Political 
shifts  resulting  from  such  a  relocation  can  not  be  assessed  at  the  moment, 
as  most  such  plans  have  not  progressed  beyond  the  blueprint  stage.  Ex- 
amples of  the  past  show  the  military  and  economic  implications  of  such 
shifts,  but  do  not  reveal  much  about  their  influence  on  politico-geographi- 
cal conditions.  The  history  of  World  War  II  offers  several  examples  of 
countries  trying  to  relocate  industries  in  areas  considered  safe,  or  rela- 
tively safe,  from  enemy  action  and  remote  from  the  frontier  zones  which 
were,  or  seemed  to  be,  more  exposed  to  enemy  interference,  especially  by 
air  power.  In  line  with  this  kind  of  strategy,  the  Soviet  Union  withdrew 
and  re-established  important  industries  behind  the  Urals  and  in  Western 
Siberia  during  World  War  II  in  order  to  protect  them  from  conquest  or 
destruction  by  the  German  invader. 

The  new  tools  of  atomic  and  biological  warfare  provide  mankind  with 
means  of  total  destruction  which  stagger  the  imagination  and  render 
hopeless  the  task  of  rewriting  the  location  pattern  of  a  country  in  order 
to  create  areas  of  "safety." 

Actually,  none  of  the  great  powers  seems  to  have  been  able  to  work  out 
a  new  locational  pattern  for  the  purpose  of  meeting  the  threat  of  atomic 
warfare.  It  is  true  that  in  countries  like  the  Soviet  Union  and  the  United 
States  industrial  planning  in  recent  years  has  attempted  to  refrain  from 
making  the  country  as  a  whole  dependent  on  one  or  a  few  vital  industrial 
production  centers.  But  except  for  this,  preoccupation  with  the  urgent 
problems  of  the  day  has  militated  against  the  carrying  out  of  radical  plans 
for  protecting  areas  of  high  concentration  of  population  and  industry. 
So-called  "ribbon  developments"  along  the  lines  of  a  grid  of  transportation 
and  communication  lines  10  or  plans  to  set  up  small  detached  production 
units  instead  of  a  cluster  of  industries  and  to  assure  these  units  of  uninter- 
rupted transportation  have  remained  in  the  blueprint  stage.  According  to 
newspaper  reports  in  smaller  countries  with  a  more  simply  arranged  and 
highly  concentrated  industrial  location  pattern,  such  as  Sweden,  plans 
have  been  executed  successfully  to  protect  strategic  industries  by  relocat- 
ing them  underground. 

10  E.  H.  Hoover,  The  Location  of  Economic  Activity  (New  York,  1948),  p.  296. 


190  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

LOCATION  ALONG  NARROW  MARINE  STRAITS 

Another  type  of  dominating  location  has  survived  without  much  change 
in  function,  namely,  location  along  an  indispensable  route,  a  route  which 
cannot  be  by-passed,  especially  along  narrow  marine  straits.  Istanbul  and 
vicinity  along  the  Straits  (Bosporus  and  Dardanelles),  Copenhagen  on 
The  Sound  (cf.  Fig.  8-7,  p.  238),  Singapore  at  the  Straits  of  Malacca, 
Aden  at  the  entrance  to  the  Red  Sea,  and  Gibraltar  at  that  to  the  Mediter- 
ranean have  been  vital  points  for  centuries  and  are  still  so.  The  Straits 
and  The  Sound  are  in  the  hands  of  relatively  minor  powers,  Turkey  and 
Denmark,  but  other  powers  are  vitally  interested  in  their  free  use.  Among 
the  interested  powers,  Russia,  and  now  the  Soviet  Union,  has  ranked  first 
for  about  two  centuries.  This  fact  accounts  for  the  continuous  pressure 
put  by  this  power  on  the  two  smaller  nations.  Great  Britain  controls  the 
three  other  places  mentioned  and  draws  part  of  its  strength  as  a  world 
power  from  this  fact.  The  same  is  true  for  the  interoceanic  Panama  Canal, 
controlled  by  the  United  States. 

The  Suez  Canal  (cf.  Fig.  8-8,  p.  240),  in  1954,  has  ceased  to  be  a  British 
zone  of  influence  and  direct  power.  With  the  exodus  of  the  British  gar- 
rison, to  be  completed  in  1956,  Egypt  will  reach  one  of  the  goals  of  her 
national  ambition.  The  Suez  Canal  remains  an  international  waterway 
open  to  all  peaceful  navigation.  Only  the  future  can  tell  what  role  it  will 
play  in  a  serious  international  crisis  in  which  Egypt  may  have  to  take 
sides.  In  1954,  the  new  power  position  of  Egypt  in  the  Canal  Zone  was 
illustrated  by  the  fact  that  she  was  in  a  position  to  continue,  in  spite  of 
the  disapproval  of  the  United  Nations,  her  blockade  measures  against 
Israel,  in  regard  to  which  a  state  of  war  continued  to  exist. 

Turkey,  or  Egypt,  or  Denmark  cannot  help  but  be  interested  in  these 
passages  because  of  their  location  astride  them.  In  contrast,  Gibraltar, 
Singapore  (cf.  Fig.  8-5,  p.  232),  and  Aden  are  so  important  only  because 
they  have  been  transformed  deliberately  into  strongpoints  for  the  protec- 
tion of  what  has  been  called  a  vital  artery  of  the  British  Empire.11  In  the 
hands  of  weak  powers,  they  would  lose  much  of  their  importance. 

It  is  the  general  area  along  the  waterway  which  is  important,  not  a 
specific  point.  The  straits  of  Gibraltar  (cf.  Fig.  8-8,  p.  240)  were  domi- 
nated in  the  past  from  Cadiz  and  not  Gibraltar,  those  of  Malacca  from 
the  city  of  Malacca  and  not  from  Singapore.  In  both  cases  distant,  but  not 

11  C.  B.  Fawcett,  "Lifelines  of  the  British  Empire,"  in  Weigert-Stefansson-Harrison, 
op.  cit.,  pp.  238-249  (244). 


LOCATION  191 

too  distant  bases  sufficed  for  a  strong  naval  power  to  control  the  actual 
narrow  passage.  In  the  same  manner  the  United  States  supplements  its 
hold  on  the  Panama  Canal  by  its  bases  in  the  Caribbean  area  ( cf.  Fig.  3-6, 
p.  79),  such  as  the  Virgin  Islands,  Guantanamo  on  Cuba,  and  the  leased 
bases  on  Trinidad  and  other  British  islands.  Similarly  the  broad  connec- 
tion between  the  Atlantic  and  Indian  Oceans  south  of  South  Africa  is 
controlled  from  rather  distant  bases  on  the  coast  of  the  Union  of  South 
Africa,  especially  Simonstown. 

Harbors,  strategically  well-located  as  they  may  be,  if  they  are  in  the 
hands  of  powers  without  a  strong  navy  have  little  actual  value  for  the 
domination  of  these  waterways.  Neither  Spanish  Ceuta  nor  neutral  Tan- 
gier along  the  Strait  of  Gibraltar,  nor  French  Djibouti  at  the  exit  of  the 
Red  Sea,  nor  any  of  the  many  potential  island  bases  around  the  Caribbean 
Sea,  nor  the  Portuguese  Lourenco  Marques  in  South  Africa,  nor  the  Indo- 
nesian Medang  at  the  Straits  of  Malacca  are  comparable  to,  for  instance, 
Gibraltar.  The  city  of  Hormuz  which  once  dominated  the  entrance  into 
the  Persian  Gulf  has  found  no  successor.  It  is  the  peculiar  combination 
between  naval  power  and  mercantile  opportunities  that  makes  sites  along- 
side straits  so  important  and  that  explains  why  their  fortunes  change  with 
the  passage  of  time  and  changes  in  world  conditions.12 

NARROW  PASSAGES  ON  CONTINENTS 

Narrow  passages  for  traffic  exist  also  on  the  continents.  Where  long 
mountain  chains  cross  whole  continents,  pass  routes  across  these  chains 
are  of  decisive  importance.  As  a  rule  they  cannot  be  controlled  from  posi- 
tions at  some  distance,  but  only  alongside  or  astride  such  passages.  Af- 
ghanistan is  the  country  of  the  Khyber  Pass,  the  most  important  pass 
leading  from  India  to  its  Asiatic  neighbor  states.  Included  in  this  pass 
region  are  also  a  few  less  important  nearby  passes,  which  all  together 
form  this  unique  pass  zone.  The  unifying  force  of  this  route  has  proved 
strong  enough  even  in  the  present  contest  of  the  great  powers  to  preserve 
Afghanistan  as  a  political  unit. 

Similarly  Switzerland  grew  up  around  the  St.  Gotthard  Pass  and  gradu- 
ally included  some  nearby  passes.  It  is  significant  that  Switzerland  is  also 
one  of  the  few  multinational  states  which  have  withstood  so  far  the  infec- 
tion of  nationalism.  East  of  Switzerland,  Austria  developed  as  a  pass  state 
in  the  Middle  Ages  and  after  a  spectacular  development  in  the  Hapsburg 

12  For  an  elaboration  of  this  topic  and  its  strategical  implications  see  pp.  227  ff. 


EJ^  Y  p  J^j^k  -^/  <£—= 


20  40 


60 


80   Mi 


40 


80 


120    Km 

3 


— — — 1TBI  ■  MiMii'   ■■  ■'  c   ''■'*- 


JJtf 


Fig.  7-7.  The  Palestine-Syria  Corridor. 

192 


LOCATION  193 

Empire  is  reduced  again  to  an  Alpine  pass  state.  The  analogous  pass  state 
of  the  western  Alps,  Savoy,  disappeared  not  quite  a  century  ago  after  an 
existence  of  many  centuries.  The  autonomy,  acquired  for  the  Val  d'Aosta 
in  1945,  is  a  weak  aftermath.  In  contrast  it  should  be  noted  that  in  the 
long  chain  of  the  American  Cordilleras  no  pass  state  has  developed.  The 
Republic  of  Panama,  of  recent  birth,  comes  closest  to  this  concept. 

Location  around  a  pass  does  not  by  itself  signify  independence,  or  even 
different  development  of  a  region.  Quite  the  opposite,  such  pass  areas  are 
much  sought  after  and  coveted  by  adjacent  countries  in  the  plains.  The 
easier  the  route  through  them,  the  easier  they  fall  prey.  The  Iroquois  were 
able  to  base  their  federation  on  the  gap  of  the  Mohawk  valley  through  the 
Appalachians,  but  this  political  body  did  not  exist  very  long.  Many  others 
never  became  the  center  of  states.  One  such  gap,  which  has  long  been 
a  cradle  of  conflict— the  area  around  Trieste— either  belonged  to  some 
strong  state  or  was  divided  between  two  of  them.  It  was  too  important 
to  be  left  to  the  control  of  the  local  inhabitants,  and  too  wide  and  open 
for  them  to  preserve  their  independence  against  other  strong  powers. 
There  are  other  such  pass  regions.  One  of  the  most  fateful  in  European 
history  is  the  gap  between  the  southern  end  of  the  Urals  and  the  northern 
end  of  the  Caspian  Sea  which  opens  into  the  steppes  of  Central  Asia.  Too 
broad  and  flat  to  be  defensible,  it  proved  to  be  definite  enough  to  channel- 
ize movement  of  nomadic  tribes.  Time  and  again  Huns,  Magyars,  Tatars 
and  many  others  broke  into  Europe,  and  occasionally  mass  movements  in 
the  opposite  direction  also  occurred.  However,  the  Russian  peasants  mi- 
grated into  Siberia  in  numbers  of  many  hundreds  of  thousands  not 
through  this  gate  but  over  low  passes  farther  north  in  the  Urals.  Today 
this  region,  though  not  very  far  from  the  geometrical  center  of  the  Soviet 
Union,  is  still  a  region  off  the  main  roads. 

The  same  fateful  role  which  the  Ural-Caspian  gate  plays  in  European 
history  was  assigned  to  the  Palestinian-Syrian  corridor  in  the  history  of 
the  Near  East  ( Fig.  7-7 ) .  It  is  a  narrow  piece  of  cultivable  land  between 
the  Arabian  desert  and  the  Mediterranean  Sea  connecting  Egypt  with  the 
mountains  of  Asia  Minor  and  the  fertile  plains  of  Iraq.  Nomads  and  other 
peoples,  forced  to  migrate,  have  used  it  since  prehistoric  times.  Merchants 
and  other  peaceful  travelers  followed.  Armies  trod  the  corridors  under 
obscure  leaders  or  under  world-famous  generals  and  kings  from  the  Ram- 
ses and  Alexander  to  Napoleon  and  Allenby.  A  number  of  nations  have 
tried  to  make  their  home  in  this  corridor  and  defend  themselves  in  its 
narrow  confines  and  its  rugged  hills  and  mountains.  Recurrent  wars  and 
annihilating  catastrophes  were  their  repeated  fate. 


194  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

A  much  broader  corridor  that  time  and  again  played  a  role  of  fateful 
importance  in  European  history  is  the  western  continuation  of  the  broad 
Russian  Plain  through  Poland,  Northern  Germany,  Belgium,  and  into 
western  France.  Cultural  influences,  tribes  and  nations,  commerce  and 
armies  have  moved  through  this  corridor.  Large  rivers  cross  it,  and  at  the 
few  points  where  these  rivers  can  be  crossed,  important  cities  have  sprung 
into  existence.  In  its  narrowest  part— in  Flanders— the  meeting  of  diverse 
influences  has  created  one  of  the  centers  of  European  civilization.  Here 
also  an  unusually  large  number  of  famous  battlefields  can  be  found. 

Parallel  to  this  corridor  there  is  another  south  of  the  Alps,  the  Po  valley. 
However,  the  great  centers  of  civilization  are  neither  west  nor  east  of  it, 
but  Rome  to  the  south  and  the  French  and  German  core  areas-  to  the  north 
of  it.  The  stream  of  east-west  movement  in  the  corridor  was  crossed  by 
a  more  important  one  on  the  points  where  routes  over  the  Alps  and  the 
Appenines  open.  The  great  centers  tend  to  lie  on  such  cross  routes. 

ISTHMUSES 

Isthmuses,  those  narrow  pieces  of  land  which  connect  two  continents 
or  larger  land  masses,  look  on  the  map  like  natural  corridors.  Only  detailed 
maps  show  that  this  is  rarely  the  case.  The  Isthmus  of  Panama,  or  even 
the  whole  of  Central  America,  have  never  served  as  a  corridor  between 
North  and  South  America.  High  rugged  mountains  and  the  unhealthy 
climate  of  the  lower  parts  account  for  this.  It  is  still  debated  whether  the 
two  pre-Columbian  high  civilizations  of  the  Mayas  and  the  Incas  had  any 
contact  over  this  land  route.  The  Pan-American  highway  system  is  still 
incomplete.13 

Other  isthmuses,  like  that  of  Kra  at  the  base  of  the  Malayan  peninsula 
(cf.  Fig.  8-5,  p.  232),  are  only  slightly  favorable  for  the  movement  of  men 
and  goods.  Cultural  influences  and  invaders  entered  the  Greek  Pelopon- 
nesus and  the  Crimea,  to  name  only  two  examples,  as  often  across  the 
narrow  sea  as  through  the  isthmuses  which  connect  these  peninsulas  with 
the  mainland. 

More  important  than  the  negative  function  of  isthmuses  as  land  routes 
is  the  fact  that  the  narrow  waist  of  an  isthmus  is  a  minor  obstacle  for 
crossing  from  sea  to  sea.  The  construction  of  canals  only  accentuates  a 
pre-existing  favorable  condition.  The  canals  of  Suez  and  Panama  are  the 
two  main  examples. 


13 


See  Fig.  22-1,  p.  670. 


LOCATION  195 

ISTHMUSES  AND  CANALS:  SUEZ  AND  PANAMA 

The  Suez  Canal  (cf.  Fig.  8-8,  p.  240)  cuts  through  the  only  isthmus 
which  is  a  major  historical  highway.  This  canal  separates  the  Eurasian 
and  African  landmasses,  connecting  the  Mediterranean  at  Port  Said  with 
the  Red  Sea  at  Suez  over  the  short  distance  of  about  one  hundred  miles. 
This  short  cut  which  obviates  the  necessity  of  transloading  has  completely 
replaced  the  old  land  route  from  Alexandria  to  the  Red  Sea,  as  well  as 
that  from  the  Syrian  ports  to  Basra  at  the  Persian  Gulf.  It  has,  thereby, 
increased  the  key  position  of  Egypt  and  Sinai,  and  made  Syria's  position 
as  an  intermediary  between  East  and  West  a  matter  of  the  past,  impair- 
ing its  standing  among  the  countries  of  the  Near  East.  During  recent 
decades,  however,  the  construction  of  pipelines  from  Iraq  and  Saudi 
Arabia  to  the  Syrian  and  Lebanese  ports  has  tended  to  return  to  Syria 
some  part  of  its  key  position. 

Constructed  by  the  French,  the  Suez  Canal  has  been  under  British 
control  from  1875  to  1954,  a  period  roughly  contemporary  with  the  flour- 
ishing of  the  so-called  third  British  Empire.  As  long  as  India  was  an  in- 
tegral part  of  this  Empire  the  Suez  Canal  was  indispensable  to  it  and  has 
long  been  an  important  link  in  the  "life  line"  starting  at  Gibraltar  in  the 
West  and  leading  into  the  Indian  Ocean  at  Aden.  During  and  after  World 
War  II  India,  Pakistan,  Burma,  and  Ceylon  loosened  their  ties  with  Great 
Britain.  As  a  result,  the  Canal,  though  still  a  valuable  asset,  is  no  longer 
the  indispensable  link.  At  the  same  time  the  development  of  air  power  has 
made  the  Canal  vulnerable  to  enemy  attack.  With  the  transfer  of  the 
Canal  to  Egypt  the  Canal  and  the  country  on  its  banks  is  in  the  hand  of 
the  same  power.  Its  control  has  strengthened  the  position  of  Egypt,  both 
economically  and  politically. 

The  Panama  Canal  (cf.  Fig.  3-6,  p.  72)  offers  an  interesting  similar 
example.  Though  of  equally  great  importance,  the  isthmus  of  Panama  in 
the  hands  of  weak  and  small  nations,  first  Colombia,  later  of  the  Republic 
of  Panama,  was  rather  a  cause  of  weakness  for  these  countries.  Like  the 
Suez  Canal,  the  Panama  Canal  has  great  importance  for  international 
commerce.  Its  role  is  even  more  significant  than  that  of  the  Suez  Canal 
because  of  its  importance  for  the  commerce  and  the  political  position  of 
the  United  States.  However,  while  the  Suez  Canal  could  justly  be  called 
a  part  of  the  life  line  of  the  British  Empire,  the  cohesion  of  the  United 
States  would  not  be  threatened  without  the  Panama  Canal.  It  enables  the 
United  States  Navy  to  operate  the  American  fleet  in  two  oceans  and  to 
concentrate  naval  strength  in  the  face  of  the  greatest  danger.  Because  of 


196  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

this  hemispheric  defense  role  of  the  Panama  Canal,  the  United  States  has 
established  bases  for  the  protection  of  the  Canal  on  the  island  approaches 
in  the  Caribbean  and  in  the  Pacific.  This  necessitated  a  change  in  its 
political  relations  to  the  areas  concerned,  which  were  either  British  col- 
onies or  independent  states.  It  has  strengthened  the  economic  and  polit- 
ical ties  in  all  cases,  but  it  has  also  evoked  unfavorable  repercussions. 
Some  groups  in  the  Republic  of  Panama  could  base  their  political  prestige 
on  the  popularity  of  the  fight  against  encroachment  by  the  Americans. 
However,  nowhere  did  the  opposition  take  forms  of  open  hostility  com- 
parable to  that  shown  by  the  Greek  majority  on  Cyprus  since  the  British 
have  shifted  their  Suez  Canal  installations  to  this  island. 

The  Panama  Canal  was  not  the  only  canal  site  which  has  been  con- 
sidered by  the  Americas  at  one  time  or  another.  Canals  have  been  pro- 
posed across  Nicaragua,  Honduras,  and  across  Mexico's  Isthmus  of 
Tehuantepec.  Probably  earliest  was  the  proposal  to  use  the  Atrato  River 
and  on  the  Pacific  side  the  San  Juan  River.  While  this  project  never 
came  near  serious  consideration,  primarily  because  of  geographical  and 
technical  difficulties,  in  all  the  other  proposals  political  considerations 
were  at  least  as  important  as  the  technical  problems,  and  all  were  so  inti- 
mately interwoven  that  they  can  not  well  be  separated  in  the  discussion. 
Perhaps  the  clearest  case  is  that  of  the  Tehuantepec  project  which  would 
have  put  American  forces,  already  deployed  along  the  northern  boundary 
of  Mexico,  into  the  southern  frontier  zone  and  would  have  deprived  this 
country  potentially  of  all  direct  contact  with  any  other  neighbor.  What 
was  tolerable  and  even  to  a  certain  degree  an  insurance  for  its  independ- 
ence for  such  a  small  country  as  Panama,  would  have  been  considered  an 
impairment  of  its  sovereignty  by  a  larger  country  with  the  proud  tradition 
of  Mexico. 

THE  KRA  CANAL  PROJECT 

The  Kra  isthmus  on  the  Malayan  Peninsula  ( cf.  Fig.  8-5,  p.  232 )  is  the 
potential  site  of  an  interoceanic  canal.  Though  plans  for  such  a  canal 
never  have  passed  beyond  the  blueprint  stage,  their  existence  alone  has 
been  helpful  for  Thailand  in  its  struggle  to  maintain  its  independent 
buffer  position  against  France,  Britain,  and  Japan.  Opposed  to  such  a 
canal  were  the  local  interests  of  Singapore  and  the  larger  interests  of 
Great  Britain,  whose  supervision  of  the  traffic  through  the  Strait  of 
Malacca  would  be  challenged.  The  construction  of  a  canal  through  the 
Isthmus  of  Kra  would  shorten  the  route  around  the  Malayan  Peninsula  by 
600  miles  and,  therefore,  despite  canal  fees,  be  a  heavy  competitor  of  the 


LOCATION  197 

Singapore  route.  The  importance  of  Singapore  is  only  about  150  years  old. 
Before  the  advent  of  the  Europeans  in  the  sixteenth  century  and  also 
later,  as  long  as  shipping  preferred  routes  not  too  far  from  land,  the  route 
from  the  Indian  Ocean  to  the  South  China  Sea  led  this  way.  The  route 
was  dominated  by  a  site  farther  north,  that  of  the  city  of  Malacca.  When 
the  Dutch  came  and  ventured  a  direct  route  from  the  Cape  of  Good  Hope 
across  the  Indian  Ocean,  the  Sunda  Strait  and  Batavia  grew  in  impor- 
tance. Singapore's  importance  was  finally  confirmed  when  the  opening  of 
the  Suez  Canal  made  the  northerly  straits  the  more  convenient  route  to 
the  Far  East. 

The  minor  importance  of  the  Kra  route,  and  that  of  the  only  other  exist- 
ing interoceanic  canal,  that  of  Kiel  in  Germany  at  the  base  of  the  Jutland 
Peninsula,  is  geographically  caused  by  the  fact  that  the  saving  in  shipping 
time  is  relatively  small  compared  with  that  brought  about  by  the  con- 
struction of  the  Suez  and  Panama  canals.  The  latter  obviate  the  necessitv 
of  circumnavigating  a  whole  continent,  the  first  two  only  of  peninsulas. 

PENINSULAS 

The  importance  of  peninsulas  must  be  seen  in  their  isolation  potential 
caused  by  their  semidetachment.  This  sometimes  meant  that  these  penin- 
sulas remained  culturally  backward  and  politically  of  little  importance. 
A  striking  example  is  that  of  the  peninsula  of  Lower  California,  where 
isolation  is  aggravated  by  a  desert  or  semidesert  climate.  As  early  as  in 
pre-Columbian  times  it  was  inhabited  by  one  of  the  most  backward  Indian 
groups  and  this  backwardness,  in  relation  to  other  parts  of  Mexico,  has 
remained  characteristic.  Even  in  Europe  some  peninsulas,  such  as  Corn- 
wall, Wales,  or  Brittany,  have  been  able  to  preserve  their  identity,  even 
some  remnants  of  a  separate  nationality,  but  have  remained  somewhat 
backward.  Mountains,  everywhere  in  the  world  favored  as  refuge  areas, 
accentuate  this  function  of  peninsulas— and  of  islands— because  there  is  no 
longer  any  other  possibility  of  retreat. 

In  large  peninsulas  we  speak  of  favorable  conditions  for  development 
of  separate  nationalities  and  independent  states  such  as  Italy,  Spain  to- 
gether with  Portugal,  Denmark,  or  Korea.  However,  this  condition  should 
not  be  overrated,  as  the  long  history  of  political  divisions  in  Italy,  the 
Iberian  Peninsula,  and  even  in  Korea  shows.  The  Balkan  Peninsula, 
Arabia,  and  others  never  accomplished  political  unification. 

However,  due  to  the  geographical  accident  that  many  peninsulas  are 
continental  protrusions  reaching  close  to  some  other  continent,  historically 


198  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

the  most  important  function  of  peninsulas  has  been  that  of  steppingstones 
for  migrations  and  invasions.  From  the  prehistoric  immigration  of  man 
into  the  Western  hemisphere  by  way  of  the  Chukotsk  peninsula  of  north- 
eastern Asia  and  Alaska,  and  into  Europe  by  way  of  the  Iberian  Peninsula 
—and  through  the  lowland  between  the  Urals  and  the  Caspian  Sea— to  the 
invasion  of  Europe  by  the  Allies  through  the  Italian  Peninsula  and  Nor- 
mandy there  is  a  continuous  stream  of  such  movements.  Oriental  ancient 
civilization  found  its  way  west  along  the  coasts  of  Asia  Minor  and  Greece. 
This  bridge  situation  has  created  a  psychological  and  political  attitude 
which  is  similar  to  the  buffer-state  psychology,  but  differs  in  that  the  polit- 
ical bodies  on  such  peninsulas  feel— rightly  or  often  wrongly— much  more 
secure,  and  very  often  culturally  superior.  Koreans,  Greeks,  Italians,  and 
even  Spaniards  have  displayed  this  feeling  of  superiority,  and  it  has  led, 
sometimes,  to  disastrous  overestimation  of  their  own  political  potentiali- 
ties. Italy's  dream  of  a  mare  nostro  is  only  the  last  instance. 

ISLAND  CHAINS  AND  LAND  BRIDGES 

Much  better  steppingstones  for  cultural  or  migratory  movements  have 
been  provided  by  island  chains.  As  a  rule,  such  island  chains  are  open 
from  all  sides,  thus  inviting  invasion  at  many  points.  In  Japan,  cultural 
influences  have  entered  as  well  through  the  harbor  of  Nagasaki  at  the 
southern  end  as  through  Tokyo,  situated  roughly  in  the  center  of  the 
chain.  Land  bridges,  though  mostly  entered  from  the  end,  can  be  open  to 
occasional  invasion  from  the  sides.  People  moving  through  such  a  corridor 
are  confined  to  it  by  the  accompanying  mountains,  sea,  or  desert.  Thus 
they  are  open  to  attack  from  the  flank  by  raiders  striking  from  the  desert 
or  from  the  sea,  who  are  accustomed  and  equipped  to  move  through  these 
inhospitable  spaces.  Syria  and  Palestine  are  the  classical  examples  of  such 
a  corridor,  attacked  time  and  again  by  the  wandering  nomads  of  steppe 
and  desert  from  the  east,  and  from  the  west  by  seaborne  invaders.  The 
days  of  nomadic  invaders  are  apparently  past.  However,  modern  Jews 
have  followed  the  path  of  Philistines  and  Crusaders  who,  coming  from 
beyond  the  Mediterranean,  founded  a  state  based  on  the  coast,  but  like 
their  predecessors  are  unable  to  control  the  entire  width  of  the  corridor. 

SEACOASTS  OF  CONTINENTS 

Seacoasts,  depending  on  their  physical  character  and  configuration,  are 
open  to  raid  and  invasion  to  a  smaller  or  larger  degree.  Invasion  across 
the  sea  is  a  powerful  factor  in  the  history  of  modern  states.  Almost  all  the 


LOCATION  199 

states  of  the  Americas,  Australia,  and  New  Zealand,  as  well  as  most  of  the 
colonies  or  semi-independent  political  bodies  of  Africa  bear  the  mark  of 
their  maritime  origin  in  the  distribution  of  their  populations,  cities,  re- 
ligions, and  cultural  ties.  Coasts,  of  course,  differ  greatly  in  terms  of 
accessibility.  The  Atlantic  coasts  of  North  and  South  America  are  easily 
accessible  and  natural  harbors  are  within  easy  distance  of  each  other.  On 
the  other  hand,  many  African  coasts  are  exposed  to  heavy  surf,  have  few 
natural  indentations,  and  are  backed  by  almost  impenetrable,  dense,  wet 
forests.  No  seafaring  nations  grew  up  on  any  part  of  this  coast.  The  factor 
of  distance  from  other  coasts,  and  especially  from  any  opposite  shore  at 
a  reasonable  distance,  contributed  to  render  these  coasts  of  West  Africa 
a  backwater  of  history.  Even  when  the  Europeans  appeared,  they  occu- 
pied only  a  few  coastal  points  and  built  forts  where  slaves  were  collected 
for  shipment  to  America.  The  invaders  were  kept  from  penetrating  inland 
by  the  forests,  swamps,  and  diseases  of  the  coastal  plain,  as  well  as  by  the 
slopes  of  the  plateau  and  the  cataracts  of  the  rivers  farther  inland.  The 
resistance  of  the  natives  could  be  discounted. 

It  is  interesting  to  compare  with  these  West  African  coasts  those  in  East 
Africa  in  approximately  the  same  latitude.  The  general  character  of  the 
coast  is  similar,  though  there  are  a  few  more  natural  harbors  in  the  east. 
The  immediate  hinterland  is  similarly  uninviting.  Well-organized  native 
states  nowhere  reached  to  the  coasts.  However,  West  Africa  remained 
apart  from  the  currents  of  world  history  to  the  end  of  the  nineteenth 
century,  when  the  scattered  trading  posts  finally  developed  into  exploita- 
tion colonies  where  raw  materials  were  developed  systematically,  native 
labor  trained,  and  markets  for  European  products  found.  In  East  Africa 
this  condition  had  been  reached  almost  one  thousand  years  ago  and 
mass  colonization  from  overseas  had  even  been  attempted.  The  decisive 
distinguishing  factor  is  that  East  Africa  is  close  to  coasts  where  seafar- 
ing peoples  have  developed.  Since  the  times  of  the  ancient  Egyptians, 
traders  and  occasionally  colonists  have  come  continuously  to  these 
coasts.  Though  neither  colonizing  Arabs  nor  Europeans  ever  came  in 
great  numbers,  the  Arabs  to  the  coast,  the  Europeans  to  the  Kenya  High- 
lands, they  have  won  a  firm  foothold.  Perhaps  numerically  strongest  was 
the  invasion  of  Madagascar  by  Malayans  from  the  opposite  shores  of 
Indonesia.  Though  large,  the  Indian  Ocean  proved  to  be  not  too  large 
to  prevent  its  crossing  by  men  in  considerable  numbers  even  before  the 
age  of  the  modern  ship.  Thus  it  was  nothing  specifically  novel  when  the 
British  founded  their  circum-oceanic  empire  around  the  Indian  Ocean 
in  the  nineteenth  century. 


200  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

There  are  no  shores  which  have  no  opposite  shore,  in  geometrical 
terms.  For  practical  purposes,  however,  the  Pacific  Ocean  is  so  wide  that 
neither  Chile  nor  Peru  have  ever  been  influenced  in  their  political  think- 
ing by  the  awareness  of  their  opposite  shore.  The  same  is  true  of  those 
shores  of  Eurasia  and  North  America  which  face  the  Arctic  Ocean.  In 
the  days  of  the  "air  age,"  this  situation  is  changing  rapidly  and  Americans 
have  discovered  to  their  discomfort  how  close  is  the  opposite  shore  across 
the  frozen  sea  for  military  aircraft.  The  importance  of  new  locational 
factors  in  the  Arctic  regions  is  discussed  in  Chapter  8. 

COASTS  OF  ISLANDS 

What  is  true  for  the  coasts  of  continents  is  equally  valid  for  coasts  of 
islands.  The  British  Isles  afford  an  example  which  is  of  interest  in  more 
than  one  respect.  The  close  proximity  of  the  European  continent  to  the 
southeastern  coast  of  Great  Britain  made  this  coast  the  repeated  entrance 
for  invaders  and  the  earliest  inhabitants  were  pushed  northwestwards 
into  the  mountains.  Vestiges  of  these  subsequent  invasions  can  be  found 
in  many  peculiarities  of  the  cultural  landscape.  But  politically  only  the 
Irish  in  Eire  have  been  able  to  shape  the  map,  and  to  a  slight  degree 
the  Celtic-speaking  remnants  in  Wales  and  the  Scottish  Highlands.  In 
Ireland  the  struggle  between  the  invaders  and  the  indigenous  Celtic 
group  is  still  going  on.  Despite  the  apparent  victory  of  the  Irish,  it  should 
not  be  forgotten  that  the  English  language  is  spoken  by  the  majority  and 
that  it  is  far  from  decided  whether  it  will  lose  or  win  ground  in  the  com- 
ing decades.14  Ireland's  north,  west,  and  south  coasts  and  the  western 
coast  of  Great  Britain,  facing  the  apparently  endless  ocean,  were  a  coast 
without  an  opposite  coast  up  to  the  time  of  Columbus.  It  was  close 
enough  to  the  European  continent  that  Vikings  could  attack  and  even 
settle  here.  That  remained  an  isolated  instance.  After  the  discovery  of 
America  the  west  coast  of  Great  Britain  lost  this  character  of  a  back 
door,  but  the  Irish  western  coast  largely  retained  it. 

ISLANDS  AS  AREAS  OF  REFUGE 

Despite  this  threat  of  invasion  due  to  their  location,  many  islands  have 
become  refuge  areas.  The  Irish  in  Ireland,  the  Ainos  on  Hokkaido,  the 
aborigines  in  a  Chinese  Formosa,  or  the  Singhalese  on  Ceylon  are  island 
peoples  in  areas  of  refuge  and  it  is  little  realized  that  all  these  peoples 

"See  pp.  392  ff. 


LOCATION  201 

once  occupied  much  larger  areas.  They  have  tended  to  develop  special 
traits,  or  rather  to  retain  older  traits  which  have  disappeared  elsewhere. 
The  language  spoken  by  the  people  of  Iceland  is  much  closer  to  the 
Norwegian  spoken  a  thousand  years  ago  in  Norway  than  is  the  modern 
Norwegian.  The  Eskimos  of  Greenland,  until  quite  recently,  were  able 
to  preserve  old  customs  over  many  centuries.  Islands  have  often,  and 
partly  because  of  these  cultural  peculiarities,  retained  a  special  political 
status  even  when  conquered.  Such  conquests  did  not  always  come  from 
culturally  related  nations  nearby,  but  from  countries  far  away.  Malta, 
Cyprus,  or  Ceylon  are  bound  to  the  British  Isles  under  different  consti- 
tutional forms;  Madagascar  belongs  to  France,  although  it  is  far  from 
France  as  well  as  from  any  other  French  colony;  Sicily  has  its  separate 
status  within  Italy;  Ireland,  Iceland,  Cuba,  Santo  Domingo  have  attained 
independence  after  centuries  of  foreign  rule. 

It  would,  however,  be  misleading  to  regard  islands  as  refuge  areas  by 
their  very  location  in  the  midst  of  the  sea.  Many  islands  are  not  refuge 
areas  at  all.  Others  are  refuge  areas  not  as  such,  but  because  their 
mountains  have  offered  the  sought-for  protection.  Ceylon,  separated  from 
India  by  a  strait  only  some  twenty  miles  wide,  is  an  especially  clear  ex- 
ample. Here  the  primitive,  dark-skinned,  small  Veddas  live  in  the  least 
accessible  parts;  the  Singhalese  have  retreated  to  the  mountains  and  the 
southern  parts  of  the  islands,  while  the  northern  half  of  the  island  was 
invaded  by  Tamils.  They  in  turn  were  confined  to  dry,  mountainous  areas 
by  Singhalese  recovery.  The  latest  to  come  were  people  from  different 
parts  of  southern  India  and  some  Europeans.  Like  the  Irish,  the  Sin- 
ghalese seem  to  have  succeeded  in  reasserting  their  preponderance  on 
the  island.  However,  Ceylon  is  a  refuge  area  also  in  another  sense.  This 
is  the  only  part  of  the  Indian  subcontinent  where  Buddhism  remained 
the  dominating  faith.  The  historical  background  is  reflected  in  its  politi- 
cal status  since  1948  as  an  independent  nation,  although  retaining  some 
ties  to  Great  Britain  as  well  as  to  India.  While  India  was  able  to  absorb 
mainland  areas  of  very  different  background,  such  as  those  of  the  hill 
tribes,  and  gave  up  other  areas  to  Pakistan  only  after  prolonged  struggle, 
it  permitted  Ceylon  to  go  its  own  way.  The  geographic  factors  of  in- 
sularity, of  the  physical  qualities  of  the  island,  and  of  its  prominent  posi- 
tion on  vital  shipping  lanes  in  the  Indian  Ocean  account  for  Ceylon's 
being  able  to  chart  its  own  political  course,  independent  of  India.15 

Another  example  of  islands   as  the  basis   of  independent  statehood, 

15  B.  H.  Farmer  in  O.  H.  K.  Spate,  Geography  of  India  and  Pakistan  (London, 
1954),  pp.  743  and  782. 


202  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

although  it  has  still  to  pass  the  test  of  history,  is  offered  by  the  South 
Moluccas  (also  called  the  Spice  Islands),  where  a  secessionist  "South 
Moluccas  Republic"  was  established  in  1950  (cf.  Fig.  3-5,  p.  70).  Indo- 
nesia, which  had  gained  independence  from  the  Netherlands  in  1949, 
recaptured  the  port  of  Amboina  where  the  secessionist  movement  origi- 
nated, but  the  rebels  escaped  to  the  island  of  Ceram  and  neighboring 
islands  where  they  have  continued  to  resist.16  One  important  feature  in 
the  current  struggle  between  Indonesia  and  the  South  Moluccas  is  the 
religious  cleavage,  since  Indonesian  nationalism  was  essentially  a  Java- 
nese movement  in  its  early  stages,  and  as  such  closely  associated  with  the 
Moslem  religion,  while  the  pagan  population  of  Amboina  and  the  neigh- 
boring islands,  isolated  from  the  main  islands,  had  been  converted  to 
Christianity  by  the  Dutch.17  Afraid  of  mass  immigration  from  overpop- 
ulated  Java,  the  people  of  the  South  Moluccas  have  chosen  to  resist  the 
substitution  of  Dutch  by  Javanese  rule  in  their  island  refuges. 

Another  example  is  offered  by  Formosa.  The  native  population  was 
displaced  and  forced  into  the  mountains  by  numerically  overwhelming 
Chinese,  and  during  the  Japanese  rule,  by  Japanese  immigration.  How- 
ever, recently,  even  their  hold  on  their  mountain  refuge  seems  to  weaken. 
Numerically  the  situation  appears  hopeless.  While  the  number  of  the 
156,000  aborigines,  reported  in  1938,  remains  almost  stationary,  the 
Chinese  population  increased  from  3,156,000  in  1905  to  5,747,000  (plus 
308,000  Japanese)  in  1938,  and  to  8,000,000,  which  is  the  estimate  in 
1955.  More  significant,  Formosa  now  for  the  second,  time  has  become  a 
refuge  area  for  traditional  China.  The  first  instance  occurred  in  the  sev- 
enteenth century,  after  the  Manchus  had  overrun  the  mainland,  the 
second  in  our  own  time  in  the  face  of  Communist  rule  on  the  mainland. 

REFUGE  AREAS  ON  CONTINENTS 

The  problem  of  the  Formosan  aborigines  in  a  refuge  area  for  a  primi- 
tive group  is  not  so  much  that  of  an  island  as  a  problem  within  an  island. 
In  that  it  is  not  different  from  the  problems  of  other  primitive  groups,  such 
as  the  Veddas  in  Ceylon,  the  Ainus  in  Hokkaido,  the  Dyaks  in  Borneo,  the 
Igorots  in  Luzon,  and  many  others.  In  all  these  instances  mountains 
and  forests  rather  than  the  islands  themselves  offered  the  refuge  area 
both  for  culturally  backward  and  for  numerically  weak  populations.  On 
the  continents  such  mountain  refuges  and  forest  areas  were  sought  out 

16  See  Fig.  3-5,  p.  70. 

17  See  pp.  423  ff. 


LOCATION  203 

by  small  groups,  and  served  in  a  few  cases  to  shelter  independent  states.18 
Ethiopia  and  Nepal  are  the  best  remaining  examples,  or  among  highly 
civilized  nations,  Switzerland.  More  frequent  are  instances  where  such 
units  have  preserved  some  form  of  autonomous  self-government  under 
foreign  domination.  The  autonomous  Soviet  republics  in  the  Caucasus, 
or  the  Basque  area  in  Spain  are  well-known  examples.  Less  known  is  the 
case  of  the  "Autonomous  Region"  which  the  Rumanian  constitution  of 
1952  granted  to  a  Hungarian  minority  in  northeastern  Transylvania.  It 
seems  significant  that  this  autonomy  was  not  granted  to  the  majority  oi 
Hungarians  within  the  confines  of  Rumania,  but  to  these  so-called  Sziks 
(Szeklers)  who  form  only  about  two-fifths  of  the  Hungarian  minority  in 
Rumania,  but  have  led  a  separate  existence  in  their  mountains  since  the 
tenth  century.  In  the  diet  of  Transylvania  they  formed  a  separate  nation 
from  the  Magyars  (Hungarians)  until  1848. 

It  is  improbable  that  a  new  state  would  arise  today  and  receive  its 
shape  from  such  local  conditions  of  topography.  That  states  formed  under 
primitive  conditions  in  the  protection  of  mountains  and  forests  have  been 
able  to  survive  into  the  present  is  largely  due  to  the  power  of  tradition 
and  to  the  national  pride  which  prompts  people  to  cling  to  every  piece 
of  land  they  have  inherited,  or  even  to  the  fact  that  divisive  features  in 
the  landscape  have  developed  because  there  was  a  boundary.  In  con- 
trast, Poland  offers  an  example  of  a  nation  with  very  strong  national 
concepts  and  traditions  but  without  the  benefit  of  established  boundaries 
fortified  by  physical  features.  The  boundary  changes  which  took  place 
after  World  War  II  were  the  result  of  its  precarious  location  between  the 
U.S.S.R.  and  Germany  and  of  its  new  status  as  a  Soviet  satellite  (cf.  Fig. 
4-1,  p.  82).  Poland  its  industrial  and  agricultural  base  and  its  population 
were  moved  many  miles  westwards  in  a  generally  featureless  plain.  Only 
its  southern  mountain  boundary  along  the  Carpathians  remained  basically 
unchanged. 

The  classical  example  of  a  state  whose  boundaries  seem  to  conform  to 
a  mountain  configuration  is  Bohemia,  the  western  part  of  the  Czecho- 
slovakian  republic.  The  Slavic  tribes,  which  coalesced  to  the  Czech  people 
in  the  early  Middle  Ages,  settled  in  the  treeless,  fertile  basin  where  they 
enjoyed  the  protection  of  the  uninhabited,  forested  mountain  rim.  Ger- 
man colonists,  moving  east,  by-passed  this  mountain  fortress  to  the  north 
or  south,  moving  through  more  inviting  plains.  However,  these  conditions 

18  G.  B.  Cressey,  Asia's  Lands  and  People,  2nd  ed.  (New  York,  1951),  pp.  138-139; 
W.  G.  East  and  O.  H.  K.  Spate,  The  Changing  Map  of  Asia,  2nd  ed.  (New  York, 
1953),  p.  278. 


204  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

disappeared  long  ago.19  The  forests  have  been  cleared  in  wide  areas,  the 
low  mountains  are  no  longer  an  obstacle  for  modern  road  or  railroad 
construction,  and  German  settlers  penetrated  over  the  mountains  to  the 
edge  of  the  interior  basin.  Nevertheless,  the  medieval  boundary  on 
the  crest  of  the  mountains  remained  essentially  unchanged  throughout 
the  centuries.  When  Hitler  opened  the  world  conflict  and  attempted  to 
replace  the  historical  boundary  by  a  linguistic  one,  this  spelled  in  the 
end  only  disaster  for  the  Germans  within  this  boundary.  It  appears  that 
the  present  location  of  the  boundary  is  essentially  defined  by  history  and 
by  the  different  development  which  areas  take  on  the  two  sides  of  a 
long-existing  boundary,  but  that  the  location  along  ridges  has  lost  all 
independent  meaning. 

THE  ROLE  OF  DESERTS 

The  physical  factors  which  seem  least  variable  in  determining  the  loca- 
tion of  boundaries  are  deserts.  The  Sahara,  the  Gobi,  the  Rub'  al  Khali 
in  Arabia  determine  the  location  of  political  bodies  even  in  our  day.  The 
French  colonies  south  of  the  Sahara  are  clearly  different  from  the  French- 
dominated  areas  north  of  the  desert.  The  Atlas  countries  are  predomi- 
nantly settlement  colonies,  and  areas  of  political  domination,  those  south 
of  the  Sahara  are  colonies  of  economic  exploitation.  However,  even  this 
clear-cut  divisive  force  of  the  desert  may  eventually  come  to  an  end 
under  the  impact  of  modern  technical  civilization.  The  oasis  of  Buraimi 
in  the  Rub'  al  Khali  has  become  the  object  of  a  conflict  between  Saudi 
Arabia,  from  which  it  is  separated  by  hundreds  of  miles  of  sandy  desert, 
and  Oman,  from  which  it  is  separated  by  dry  inhospitable  mountains  ( cf. 
Fig.  4-3,  p.  88).  It  is,  however,  in  an  area  which  may  contain  oilfields. 
Its  importance  for  modern  technological  civilization,  and  at  the  same  time 
the  means  which  this  civilization  offers  to  overcome  the  desert,  make  this 
conflict  significant.  It  is  a  sign  that  we  may  stand  at  the  end  of  the  period 
when  deserts  were  a  nearly  insuperable  factor.  Whether  air  or  surface 
motor  transport  will  play  the  decisive  role  in  this  change  can  not  be 
predicted. 

Some  people  believe  that  the  construction  of  railroads  will  be  more  im- 
portant than  motor  or  air  transport.  This  idea  is  primarily  advanced  in 
France  by  the  promoters  of  the  construction  of  a  Trans-Saharan  railroad. 
In  any  case  the  time  seems  near  when  three  so  far  quite  disconnected 

19  J.  A.  Steers,  "The  Middle  People;  Resettlement  in  Czechoslovakia,"  Geographical 
Journal,  Vol.  102  (January,  1949). 


LOCATION  205 

centers  of  power  can  be  linked  together.  These  areas  of  present  and 
potential  power  concentration  are  the  French  North  African  territories 
(Morocco,  Algeria,  and  Tunisia),  the  Central  African  Tchad,  Ubangi. 
and  Congo  regions,  and  lastly  the  British  East  African  colonies.  Their 
linking  would  be  of  special  significance  since  these  regions  are  likely  to 
play  a  primary  role  in  a  future  conflict  involving  the  defense  of  western 
Europe  and  the  Near  and  Middle  East  against  attack  from  the  north 
and  the  east. 

SEDENTARY  AND  NOMADIC  WAYS  OF  LIFE 

To  the  same  degree  as  uninhabitable,  or  uninhabited,  or  at  least  un- 
claimed zones  tend  to  disappear,  nations  of  different  ways  of  life  become 
close  neighbors.  Thereby  the  causes  of  friction  are  greatly  increased. 
Conflicts  arising  from  different  ways  of  life  have  existed  since  times  im- 
memorial. However,  the  essential  features  of  ways  of  life  have  changed, 
too.  One  of  the  oldest  and  most  frequent  sources  of  conflict  has  been 
the  conflict  between  the  sedentary  peasant  and  the  nomadic  herdsman. 
Encroachment  of  the  land-hungry  tiller  on  the  steppe  and  pasture,  and 
raids  on  the  settlements  by  the  easily  moving  nomads  are  a  recurrent 
theme  in  all  these  border  zones  between  "sown  and  desert."  Within  the 
last  half  century  the  roving  herder  has  ceased  to  be  a  potential  threat 
to  the  peasant  settler  in  any  part  of  the  world.  Motorized  police  patrols 
and  airplanes  have  reduced  this  problem  in  the  French  Sahara  to  a  mere 
police  problem.  In  Arabia  King  Ibn  Saud  succeeded  in  settling  large 
parts  of  the  nomads  by  the  shrewd  employment  of  new  political  and 
religious  ideas.  In  Central  Asia,  the  Soviet  policy  of  totalitarianism  has 
changed  drastically  the  ways  of  life  of  nomadic  herdsmen.  In  North 
America,  under  different  conditions,  the  once-roving  Sioux,  Apaches,  and 
Comanches  now  live  in  reservations. 

THE  CONFLICT  BETWEEN  THE  COMMUNIST  AND  THE 
FREE  WORLD  IN  TERMS  OF  LOCATION 

In  place  of  these  ancient  problems  new  ones  have  arisen.  Communist 
and  non-Communist  states  must  get  along  as  close  neighbors.  While  it 
was  still  possible  after  World  War  I  to  attempt  to  minimize  frictions 
between  Communism  and  the  rest  of  the  world  by  creating  a  cordon 
sanitaire  around  the  Soviet  Union,  this  solution  has  become  obsolete 
today.  The  countries  of  South  and  East  Asia  are  for  all  practical  purposes 
close  neighbors  of  Australia  and  New  Zealand  today,  as  are  those  of 


206  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

North  America,  Asia,  and  Europe  lying  across  the  Arctic  Ocean  from  each 
other.  The  danger  of  friction  arising  from  such  location  in  close  prox- 
imity is  great. 


ADJACENT  LOCATION  OF  LARGE  AND  SMALL  NATIONS 

Adjacent  location  of  a  small  country  and  a  large  or  strong  one  always 
influences  their  relationship.  Whether  the  politics  of  the  small  country 
takes  the  form  of  more  or  less  voluntary  subordination  to  and  accommo- 
dation of  the  stronger  neighbor,  whether  it  tries  to  find  independence  in 
coalition  with  several  other  small  countries  in  a  similar  position,  or  in  an 
alliance  with  a  distant  but  strong  country,  or  whether  it  chooses  isolation 
and  withdrawal  from  all  problems  of  the  community  of  nations,  depends 
on  many  nonlocational  factors  and  on  their  interplay  with  the  implica- 
tions of  location.  Mexico  is  a  country  that  has  tried  different  policies  in 
its  relations  with  its  neighbor  in  the  north— from  invoking  the  sympathies 
of  other  relatively  small  Latin  American  states,  to  the  more  recent  at- 
tempt to  follow  a  course  which  avoids  antagonizing  the  United  States 
without  letting  the  powerful  neighbor  actively  influence  Mexican  internal 
political  decisions.  A  great  variety  of  attitudes  is  shown  by  the  North 
European  countries  toward  the  Soviet  Union.  Finland  is  trying  hard  to 
accommodate  its  policy  to  the  whims  of  Soviet  policy,  making  it  clear 
at  the  same  time  that  she  is  not  ready  to  pay  the  high  price  of  becoming 
a  satellite.  Sweden  tries  to  steer  a  more  independent,  course.  She  is  in  a 
better  locational  position  as  she  has  no  land  boundary  with  the  Soviet 
Union  and  takes  encouragement  from  the  not  too  conclusive  fact  that 
she  succeeded  in  remaining  neutral  during  both  World  Wars.  Norway, 
on  the  other  hand,  chose  an  alliance  with  the  great  powers  of  the  West. 
An  attempt  by  Denmark  made  immediately  after  World  War  II  to  pro- 
mote an  alliance  of  the  Scandinavian  powers  was  met  by  failure. 

The  inland  country  blocked  from  access  to  the  sea  by  other  countries 
has  been  discussed  in  another  connection.  It  remains  to  mention  the  less 
frequent  situation  in  which  a  weak  country  is  pinned  between  the  sea 
and  a  strong  but  landlocked  country.  The  Baltic  republics  did  not  re- 
main free  for  long  under  such  conditions.  Another  example  is  offered  by 
the  Netherlands.  They  are  located  across  the  mouth  of  the  Rhine  which, 
although  not  the  only  outlet  to  the  sea  for  large  parts  of  Germany,  is 
by  far  the  shortest  and  best.  Skillful  statesmanship,  an  obviously  peaceful 
and  sincere  neutrality,  willingness  to  fulfill  all  reasonable  German  wishes, 
and  the  preparedness  to  refuse  any  demands  which  would  impair  Dutch 


LOCATION  207 

sovereignty  made  the  Netherlands  apparently  secure  throughout  most  of 
the  nineteenth  century  and  through  World  War  I.  Hitler,  in  World  War 
II,  upset  these  carefully  developed  balances. 

It  may  be  of  minor  importance  whether  two  countries  have  a  long  or 
short  common  border;  the  fact  that  they  border  at  all  is  of  primary 
importance  at  least  to  the  interested  parties.  In  1954,  a  flurry  of  excite- 
ment arose  when  a  Soviet  newspaper  hinted  that  in  the  high  Pamirs  the 
Soviet  Union  had  a  common  boundary  with  Kashmir,  though  in  almost 
impassable  terrain  and  for  the  length  of  a  few  miles  only.  This  would 
deny  China  direct  contact  with  Afghanistan.  China,  however,  seems  eager 
to  retain  its  common  boundary  with  Afghanistan   (cf.  Fig.  3-1,  p.  59). 


ADJACENT  LOCATION  AND  CULTURAL,  IDEOLOGICAL, 
AND  OTHER  DIFFERENCES 

Sometimes  countries  of  different  cultural  level  face  each  other  across 
the  border,  and  these  differences  can  create  political  problems.  Usually 
the  country  of  lower  economic,  technological,  or  cultural  development 
will  feel  endangered,  while  the  neighboring  country  may  embark  on  a 
"mission"  to  bring  the  advantages  of  higher  civilization  to  the  under- 
developed neighbor.  In  the  not  too  distant  past  this  took  the  form  of 
church  missionary  activity  which  in  turn  called  for  protection  by  state 
authority.  In  other  instances  merchants  and  planters  maintained  that  by 
expanding  their  occupations  they  were  spreading  European  civilization, 
lifting  natives  to  a  higher  level  by  teaching  them,  or  forcing  them,  into 
the  habit  of  regular  work.  If  they  met  with  resistance  they  appealed  to 
their  national  authorities  and  such  disputes  often  ended  in  war  and 
conquest.  At  present  the  repercussions  of  this  policy  are  felt  in  quite  dif- 
ferent ways;  they  range  from  the  relatively  minor  problems  of  the  United 
States  with  its  Indian  wards  to  the  serious  Mau  Mau  revolution  in  Kenya. 
There  are,  however,  instances  where  such  conquest  led  to  the  acceptance 
of  the  former  colonial  subjects  as  equals.  India  may  always  have  been 
spiritually  the  equal  of  Europe;  today  she  is  also  an  equal  in  economic 
methods  and  technological  approach,  even  though  much  may  still  have 
to  be  done  to  spread  technological  achievements  over  the  country.  The 
Gold  Coast  and  Nigeria  may  still  harbor  primitive  tribes,  but  they  are 
regarded  as  ready,  or  almost  ready,  to  enter  the  Commonwealth  as 
equals.  There  is  still  an  expanding  frontier  of  civilization,  and  even  of 
white  settlement  in  the  interior  of  Brazil,  in  Canada,  in  Siberia,  but  this 
is  no  longer  a  question  of  war  and  conquest,  but  an  internal  problem  of 


208  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

the  countries  concerned.  For  perhaps  the  last  time  a  Christian  power 
openly  proclaimed  its  cultural  mission  as  justification  for  conquest  when 
Italy  attacked  Ethiopia  in  1935. 

The  Soviet  Union  holds  or  at  least  proclaims  that  every  extension  of 
its  control  is  a  feat  of  liberation.  From  this  point  or  view  any  such  con- 
quest, with  whatever  means  accomplished,  is  justified  as  a  part  of 
inevitable  and  preordained  progress.  There  is,  however,  a  decisive  dif- 
ference between  Communist  conquest  and  other  conquests  accomplished 
under  the  slogan  of  civilization  for  backward  nations.  Amerindians, 
Siberian  natives,  negro  tribes  in  Inner  Africa,  and  even  Ethiopians,  though 
they  cherished  their  own  way  of  life,  regarded  Europeans  as  superior, 
at  least  in  certain  respects.  The  non-Communist  world,  on  the  other 
hand,  considers  its  way  of  life  not  only  equal  but  in  many  respects  defi- 
nitely superior  to  the  Communist  order.  As  participants  in  this  struggle 
we  may  not  claim  impartiality.  However,  the  Soviets  acknowledge  at 
least  in  some  respects  this  superiority  of  the  West,  spurring  on  their 
workers  to  imitate  and  finally  to  improve  American  methods,  concealing 
certain  aspects  of  Western  society  from  their  subjects,  keeping  them  away 
from  Western  literature  and  any  contact  with  foreigners,  showing  by 
this  method  their  actual  evaluation  of  the  attractive  features  of  Western 
civilization  which  they  could  not  denounce  as  inferior  if  free  access  to 
the  knowledge  of  Western  ways  were  possible. 

Thus  there  exist  not  only  politically  enforced  but  very  real  though 
intangible  boundaries  which  separate  people  and  areas  of  different  politi- 
cal ideology.  Where  there  are  conflicting  ideologies  each  party  is  con- 
vinced of  its  superior  way  of  life.  Confusion  between  these  two  concepts 
is  old.  The  ancient  Greeks  felt  dimly  that  the  disparity  between  their 
ways  of  life  and  those  of  the  highly  civilized  peoples  of  the  Persian  em- 
pire was  of  another  order  than  the  gulf  which  separated  their  way  of  life 
from  that  of  the  illiterate  primitive  tribes  of  most  of  Europe.  They 
recognized  that  Marathon  was  more  than  a  military-political  event,  and 
that  it  decided  for  many  centuries  to  come  which  type  of  civilization 
should  be  dominant  in  Europe.  Nevertheless,  they  persisted  in  calling 
Persians,  Egyptians,  Babylonians,  and  others  by  the  same  deprecative 
name  they  used  for  Thracians,  Numidians,  and  Celts— barbarians. 

The  main  conclusion  to  be  drawn  from  our  discussion  of  factors  of 
location  in  the  realm  of  political  geography  is  that  location  must  be  re- 
garded as  a  basic  factor  which,  certainly,  can  not  be  neglected,  but 
which  never  can  be  considered  alone.  Its  implications  are  changing  con- 
tinuously in  response  to  other  factors. 


CHAPTER 


8 


The  Impact  or  Location  on 
Strategy  and  Power  Politics 


A.    The  Heartland  and  the  Rim  Lands:  A  Study  in  Location 

Among  the  large-space  concepts  of  location  which  fascinate  the  student 
of  political  geography,  that  of  the  Heartland  has  been  most  emphasized 
in  recent  times.  It  has  received  both  enthusiastic  and  scornful  reception. 
Often  the  disciples  as  well  as  the  critics  of  the  Heartland  theory  have 
been  led  astray  by  their  unwillingness  to  recognize  the  factor  of  time 
and  change  that  erodes  this  concept  in  so  far  as  it  affects  any  other  con- 
cept of  location  in  the  fluctuating  realm  of  political  geography. 

We  propose  to  deal  at  some  length  with  the  Heartland  concept  and  to 
investigate  to  what  extent  it  has  proved  its  long-range  validity,  and  where 
in  retrospect  it  appears  to  be  depicting  only  a  temporary  situation.  As  a 
study  in  location,  the  interpretation  of  the  Heartland,  representing  a 
significant  philosophy  of  political  geography,  can  serve  to  sharpen  our 
thinking  on  factors  of  location  in  general. 

INFLUENCE  ON  POLITICO-GEOGRAPHICAL  THINKING 

Although  often  misunderstood  and  loosely  applied  by  armchair  strat- 
egists, the  Heartland  theory  has  had  nevertheless  a  profound  influence  on 
politico-geographical  thinking  in  our  time.  In  discussing  what  the  British 
geographer  Sir  Halford  J.  Mackinder  termed  in  1904  as  "the  pivot  region 
of  the  world's  politics"  ( Fig.  8-1 )  and  later  described  as  the  "Heartland" 

209 


210 


THE  IMPACT  OF  LOCATION  211 

we  shall  observe  the  truly  revolutionary  changes  of  a  world  history  in 
terms  of  geography  set  in  motion.  But  while  ten-dollar  terms  such  as 
Heartland  and  World  Island  have  been  readily  accepted  in  the  dictionary 
of  geopolitics,  they  share  the  fate  of  the  American  Security  Sphere  or  of 
the  American  Perimeter  of  Defense  in  remaining  hazy  concepts  when  it 
comes  to  exact  geographical  definition  and  evaluation.  We  must  be  care- 
ful not  to  be  found  napping  in  the  nineteenth  century  when  we  attempt 
to  organize  our  "world  view"  and  to  define  the  political  boundaries  sep- 
arating the  globe's  land  and  sea  masses  which  really  matter  in  world 
politics.  We  still  like  to  visualize  the  political  map  of  the  world  as  a 
mosaic,  the  contours  of  which  follow  the  boundaries  of  the  national  states. 
Quite  naturally  we  feel  uncomfortable  when  confronted  with  a  novel  map 
of  the  world  on  which  the  feeble  boundary  lines  and  the  colors  which 
distinguish  the  national  states  are  minimized,  with  the  emphasis  placed  on 
certain  geographical  regions  which  endow  the  powers  controlling  them 
with  the  very  assets  needed  in  the  struggle  for  world  power.  In  a  con- 
stantly and  rapidly  shrinking  political  world,  politico-geographical  en- 
tities comparable  to  the  American  security  sphere  have  achieved  a  new 
meaning  due  to  significant  changes  in  the  realm  of  transportation  and 
communication.  The  Heartland  of  Eurasia  is  therefore  more  than  a  dusty 
concept  of  the  historical  geography  of  the  Victorian  age. 

THE  HEARTLAND  CONCEPT  AND  THE 
VICTORIAN  SEA  POWER  AGE 

The  new  world  view  evolved  slowly.  Mackinder,  at  the  threshold  of 
the  new  century,  began  to  grasp  the  fact  that  the  geopolitics  of  the  Vic- 
torian age  was  no  longer  based  on  geographical  realities.  Only  if  we 
project  Mackinder's  concepts  against  the  panorama  of  the  Victorian  age, 
with  world  politics  revolving  around  Britain's  successful  struggle  for  con- 
trol of  the  high  seas  and  of  the  pathways  of  seaborne  traffic,  can  we 
perceive  the  force  of  a  new  way  of  thinking  in  which  land  power  out- 
flanked sea  power  and  new  industrial  powers  were  rising  on  the  con- 
tinent of  Eurasia.  These  concepts  loomed  large  enough  to  challenge  the 
basic  ideas  of  the  political  philosophy  and  the  political  geography  of  an 
age  of  sea  power.  The  transition  from  a  political  philosophy  revolving 
around  the  "age  of  sea  power"  concept  to  one  stressing  land  power  re- 
flects a  new  look  at  basic  factors  of  location. 

In  the  United  States,  the  political  geography  of  the  sea  power  age  had 
long  been  dominated  by  the  thinking  of  Alfred  Thayer  Mahan,  an  Ameri- 


212  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

can  naval  officer.  His  work,  The  Influence  of  Seapower  Upon  History, 
1660-1783,  is  one  of  the  rare  books  which  profoundly  affected  history. 
While  his  writings  lack  systematic  organization,  his  political  philosophy 
clearly  preaches  the  gospel  of  the  new  American  Imperialism  drawing 
its  strength  from  sea  power,  and  a  new  Manifest  Destiny  based  on 
America's  future  role  as  the  leading  maritime  nation  in  the  world— lead- 
ing, because  he  envisaged  the  day  when  the  United  States  would  replace 
Britain  in  its  rating  as  the  world's  supreme  naval  power.  The  oceans  had 
become  inland  seas  of  the  British  Empire,  and  the  trade  routes  of  the 
world  its  life  lines.  The  growing  maritime  power  of  the  United  States  was 
to  inherit  these  concepts.  Coupled  with  this  feeling  there  was  a  convic- 
tion that  power  based  upon  land  and  its  overland  transportation  systems 
could  never  compete,  either  commercially  or  stategically,  with  movement 
by  sea.1  There  is  no  doubt  that  Mahan's  doctrines  gave  a  lift  to  military 
and  political  planners  throughout  the  world  who  readily  adopted  his 
formula  for  the  achievement  of  world  power  through  sea  power.  Even 
in  Imperial  Germany,  under  Wilhelm  II,  it  kindled  a  hectic  enthusiasm 
for  what  appeared  to  be  a  new  shortcut  for  Germany  to  world  power.  It 
is  not  surprising  to  find  that  Germany's  outstanding  political  geographer 
of  these  times,  Friedrich  Ratzel,  who  had  received  a  practical  geographi- 
cal training  in  the  United  States,  published  a  book  called  The  Sea  as  a 
Source  of  National  Greatness  which  was  broadly  influenced  by  Mahan's 
thinking.2 

From  the  ramparts  of  England,  Halford  J.  Mackinder  agreed  with  the 
thinking  of  Mahan  in  one  important  aspect:  he,  too,  could  not  help 
realizing  that  Britain  had,  in  the  twentieth  century,  lost  its  leading  posi- 
tion of  naval  power  and  control  of  the  seas.  In  1901  Mackinder  wrote 
in  his  Britain  and  the  British  Seas:  "Other  empires  have  had  their  day, 
and  so  may  that  of  Britain.  But  there  are  facts  in  the  present  condition 
of  humanity  which  render  such  a  fate  unlikely,  provided  always  that  the 
British  retain  their  moral  qualities  .  .  .  the  whole  course  of  future  history 
depends  on  whether  the  Old  Britain  beside  the  Narrow  Seas  has  enough 
of  virility  and  imagination  to  withstand  all  challenge  of  her  neighbor's 
supremacy,  until  such  time  as  the  daughter  nations  shall  have  grown  to 
maturity." 

But  aside  from  agreeing  on  the  future  respective  parts  which  Britain 
and  the  United  States  were  to  play  in  the  struggle  for  naval  supremacy, 

1  H.  and  M.  Sprout,  Foundations  of  National  Power,  2nd  edition  (New  York,  1951), 
p.  154. 

2  R.  Strausz-Hupe,  Geopolitics:  The  Struggle  for  Space  and  Power  (New  York, 
1942),  p.  245. 


THE  IMPACT  OF  LOCATION  213 

the  basic  concepts  of  political  geography  of  Mahan  and  Mackinder  have 
little  in  common.  For  it  is  exactly  Mahan's  exaltation  of  sea  power  which 
was  challenged  by  Mackinder  who,  viewing  the  growing  strength  of 
Russia  and  Germany  on  the  continents,  became  more  and  more  alarmed 
by  the  challenge  to  sea  power  in  a  new  age  in  which  land  power  could 
outflank  it  and  in  which  the  mushrooming  growth  of  industrialization 
and  the  extension  of  railroad  nets  on  the  continent  were  successfully  com- 
peting with  Britain's  economic  position  in  the  world. 

THE  NEW  ROLE  OF  ASIA 

Mackinder 's  consciousness  of  the  passing  of  the  Victorian  sea  power 
age  made  him  see  Europe  and  its  political  geography  as  subordinate  to 
Asia.3  It  is  in  Asia  that  land  power  and  (as  Mackinder  did  not  anticipate 
originally)  land-based  air  power  have  had  their  greatest  opportunities  to 
challenge  established  power  positions  in  the  world  at  large.  The  mobility 
of  land  power  (not  land  power  as  such),  in  competition  with  the  mo- 
bility of  sea  power,  evolved  as  a  decisive  geopolitical  feature  of  the 
twentieth  century.  By  evaluating  the  competition  and  possible  clash  be- 
tween sea  and  land  power,  Mackinder  discovered  the  "pivot  region  of 
the  World's  politics":  the  Heartland  of  Eurasia.  He  did  not  hesitate  to 
project  the  effects  which  an  increasing  mobility  of  military  and  economic 
power  in  this  area  is  bound  to  have  on  the  rest  of  the  world.  In  1904, 
he  saw  that  "the  century  will  not  be  old  before  all  Asia  is  covered  with 
railways.  The  spaces  within  the  Russian  Empire  and  Mongolia  are  so 
vast,  and  their  potentialities  in  population,  wheat,  cotton,  fuel,  and  metals 
so  incalculably  great,  that  it  is  inevitable  that  a  vast  economic  world, 
more  or  less  apart,  will  there  develop  inaccessible  to  oceanic  commerce." 

This  pivotal  area  Mackinder  projected  as  an  organic  unit  within  the 
world  unit.  Inaccessible  to  ships  but  covered  with  a  network  of  railways, 
the  continental  basins  of  Eurasia  are  seen  as  the  homeland  of  a  new 
Russia  which  is  successor  to  the  Mongol  Empire.  From  its  central  posi- 
tion, Russia  can  exert  pressures  on  Finland,  Scandinavia,  Poland,  Turkey, 
Persia,  and  India.  The  centrifugal  force  which  drove  the  horse-riding 
nomads  of  the  steppes  westward  and  southward  against  the  settled 
peoples  of  Europe  is  still  a  living  force  in  the  Russian  Heartland.  If  ever 
it  succeeded  in  expanding  over  the  marginal  lands  of  Eurasia,  if  ever 
it  were  able  to  use  its   continental  resources  for  fleet-building,  then, 

3  H.  W.  Weigert,  Generals  and  Geographers  (New  York  and  London,  1942),  pp. 
115-139. 


214  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

Mackinder  felt,  "the  empire  of  the  world  would  be  in  sight."  And  to 
leave  no  doubt  about  the  direction  of  his  fears,  fifty  years  ago  he  added: 
"This  would  happen  if  Germany  would  ally  herself  with  Russia." 

CRITIQUE  OF  MACKINDER:  THE  HEARTLAND  AS  VIEWED 
OVER  THE  TOP  OF  THE  WORLD 

When  Mackinder,  at  the  close  of  the  first  World  War,  re-examined  his 
original  thesis  in  his  famous  address  (called  Democratic  Ideals  and 
Realities)  to  the  peacemakers  about  to  assemble  in  Paris,  he  found  that 
his  "thesis  of  1904  still  sufficed."  He  voiced  this  warning:  "Who  rules  East 
Europe  commands  the  Heartland;  Who  rules  the  Heartland  commands 
the  World  Island;  Who  rules  the  World  Island  commands  the  World." 
It  became  much  too  smooth  a  slogan  when  it  was  dusted  off  in  our  day. 
Most  of  those  who  used  it  persistently  were  fascinated  more  by  the  gen- 
eral appeal  of  the  slogan  than  by  its  geographic  realities. 

The  Heartland  of  Europe  and  Asia  had  essentially  the  same  frontiers 
in  1918  as  Mackinder's  "Pivot  Area"  of  1904.  It  comprised  the  vast  ex- 
panse of  the  continental  island  basins  of  arctic  and  continental  drainage 
which  measure  nearly  half  of  Asia  and  a  quarter  of  Europe,  and  which 
are  inaccessible  from  the  ocean.  As  a  strategical  concept,  the  Heartland 
includes  all  regions  which  can  be  denied  access  by  sea  power.  Railways, 
growing  and  expanding  inward,  have  changed  its  face  continuously  since 
1904  and  have  tested  Mackinder's  thesis.  Above  all,  the  airplane  has  since 
upset  the  unstable  balance  between  land  and  sea  power;  Mackinder 
greets  it  as  an  ally  to  land  power  in  the  Heartland. 

The  first  World  War  Mackinder  sees  as  the  climax  in  the  eternal  con- 
flict between  continental  land  power  and  marginal  power,  backed  and 
fed  by  sea  power:  "We  have  been  fighting  lately,  in  the  close  of  the  war, 
a  straight  duel  between  land  power  and  sea  power.  We  have  conquered, 
but  had  Germany  conquered  she  would  have  established  her  sea  power 
on  a  wider  basis  than  any  in  history,  and  in  fact  on  the  widest  possible 
basis." 

The  third  and  final  test  of  the  Heartland  formula  was  undertaken  by 
Mackinder  in  the  article,  "The  Round  World  and  the  Winning  of  the 
Peace,"  which  he  wrote  in  1943  for  Foreign  Affairs.*  To  Mackinder,  the 
test  was  positive;  he  found  his  concept  "more  valid  and  useful  today  than 
it  was  either  twenty  or  forty  years  ago." 

*  Foreign  Affairs  (1943),  pp.  595-605;  in  H.  W.  Weigert  and  V.  Stefansson,  eds., 
Compass  of  the  World  (New  York,  1945),  pp.  161-173. 


THE  IMPACT  OF  LOCATION  215 

Yet  while  the  original  concept  of  the  Heartland  remained  basically 
intact,  its  frontiers  were  significantly  revised.  The  revisions  were  re- 
quired in  order  to  accommodate  certain  major  changes  in  the  political 
geography  of  the  world  since  1904  and  1918.  The  territory  of  the  U.S.S.R. 
remains  equivalent  to  the  Heartland.  But  there  is  one  rather  important 
exception.  A  vast  area  within  the  Soviet  Union  which  begins  east  of  the 
Yenisei  River  and  whose  central  feature  is  the  Lena  River  has  now  been 
exempted  by  Mackinder  from  the  original  Heartland.  "Lenaland  Russia" 
has  an  area  of  three  and  three-quarter  million  square  miles  but  a  popula- 
tion of  only  some  six  millions,  in  contrast  to  "Heartland  Russia"  which 
covers  four  and  a  quarter  million  square  miles  and  has  a  rapidly  growing 
population  numbering  one  hundred  and  seventy  millions. 

Heartland  Russia,  backed  by  the  natural  resources  of  Lenaland,  fore- 
shadows greater  power  than  the  Heartland  Mackinder  envisaged  in  dec- 
ades past.  What  earlier  had  seemed  to  be  mere  speculation  had  now 
grown  into  reality,  and  Mackinder  could  state  as  a  fact  that  "except  in 
a  very  few  commodities  the  country  is  capable  of  producing  everything 
which  it  requires."  Again  he  views  the  open  western  frontier  of  the  Heart- 
land. His  conclusion  that  "if  the  Soviet  Union  emerges  from  the  war  as 
conqueror  of  Germany,  she  must  rank  as  the  greatest  land  power  on  the 
globe'"  is  slightly  less  emphatic  than  his  vision  of  the  approaching  "em- 
pire of  the  world"  ( 1904 ) .  Otherwise,  the  Britisher's  view  of  the  geo- 
political relationship  of  Russia  and  Germany  had  remained  unchanged. 

Any  attempt  at  a  critique  5  of  Mackinder's  powerful  generalizations 
should  begin  with  the  acknowledgment  of  our  indebtedness  to  the  man 
who  did  more  in  our  time  than  anybody  else  to  enlist  geography  as  an 
aid  to  statecraft  and  strategy.  The  fundamentals  of  his  closed-space  con- 
cept stand  so  firmly  today  that  we  almost  forget  how  revolutionary  the 
concept  was  when  first  formulated  forty  years  ago.  The  same  observa- 
tion applies  to  Mackinder's  land  power  thesis  which,  appearing  at  what 
seemed  to  be  the  height  of  the  Victorian  sea  power  age,  seemed  shocking 
and  fantastic  to  many  in  the  English-speaking  world.  But  in  reviewing 
his  thesis  today,  we  should  remember  that  it  is  the  concept  of  a  man 
who  viewed  the  world  from  "England  .  . .  that  utmost  corner  of  the  West." 
Only  a  Britisher  could  have  written  as  Mackinder  did.  Recognizing  this 
and  taking  account  of  the  technological  changes  which  have  surpassed 
even  Mackinder's  imagination,  we  should  have  sufficient  perspective  to- 
day to  speak  critically  of  the  theory  of  the  Heartland. 

5  Cf.  H.  W.  Weigert,  "Heartland  Revisited,"  in  H.  W.  Weigert,  V.  Stefansson,  and 
R.  E.  Harrison,  New  Compass  of  the  World  (New  York,  1949),  pp.  80-90. 


J.g.r 


Fig.  8-2.  Relationship  of  Heartland  and  North-America  on  the  Azimuthal  Polar  Projection. 


216 


THE  IMPACT  OF  LOCATION  217 

It  is  perhaps  not  incidental  that  the  logic  of  Mackinder's  Heartland 
seems  to  reveal  itself  best  on  a  Mercator  world  map  (such  as  Mackinder 
used  when  he  first  laid  out  his  blueprint).  Here  the  Heartland  lives  up 
to  its  name.  We  see  it  surrounded  by  a  huge  arc  forming  an  inner  crescent 
which  includes  Germany,  Turkey,  India,  and  China.  Beyond  the  crescent 
of  peripheral  states,  Mackinder  envisaged  an  outer  crescent  which  em- 
braced Britain,  South  Africa,  Australia,  the  United  States,  Canada,  and 
Japan.  Again  the  Mercator  projection  lent  a  helpful  hand  in  constructing 
what  seemed  to  Mackinder  a  "wholly  oceanic"  and  "insular"  crescent. 

However,  we  find  it  difficult,  if  not  impossible,  to  visualize  this  rela- 
tion of  the  Heartland  to  a  surrounding  inner  and  outer  crescent  if  we 
exchange  the  Mercator  map  for  the  globe  or  any  azimuthal-equidistant 
map  (Fig.  8-2).  The  concept  of  North  America  as  part  of  a  chain  of  in- 
sular powers  distant  from  the  Heartland  now  becomes  a  geographical 
myth.  In  terms  of  air-geography  the  Heartland  and  North  America  appear 
in  destiny-laden  proximity.  As  viewed  over  the  top  of  the  world,  the 
Heartland  assumes  a  location  different  from  that  which  Mackinder  as- 
signed to  it,  plotting  it  from  Britain,  and  with  the  destinies  of  Britain  fore- 
most in  his  mind.  While  time  has  verified  Mackinder's  concept  of  Russia's 
growing  importance  as  a  land  power  in  a  pivotal  area,  and  while  the  polit- 
ical and  military  control  of  the  U.S.S.R.  over  the  Heartland  and  Eastern 
Europe  are  at  present  more  firmly  established  than  ever,  the  skyways  of 
the  Arctic  Mediterranean  give  validity  to  a  new  way  of  regarding  the  geo- 
graphical relations  of  North  America  and  the  U.S.S.R.  The  inaccessibility 
of  the  vast  inland  spaces  of  the  Heartland  became  evident  when  the 
Heartland  power  was  attacked  by  Germany  in  the  west,  where  the  Heart- 
land opens  itself  to  invasion.  But  seen  from  North  America,  and  in  terms 
of  new  communications  reaching  out  from  many  points  in  the  far-flung 
"perimeter  of  defense"  line,  inaccessibility  and  vastness  no  longer  conceal 
the  Heartland  from  us.  It  no  longer  lies  behind  an  impenetrable  wall  of 
isolation. 

In  his  article  in  Foreign  Affairs,  Mackinder  seems  to  have  made  major 
revisions  in  his  original  concept  of  the  relationship  of  the  rest  of  the 
world  to  the  Heartland.  We  have  noticed  that  the  original  Heartland 
thesis  remained  basically  unaltered,  although  the  emphasis  on  the  thinly 
populated  Lenaland  area  has  been  toned  down.  But  the  surrounding 
crescents  (and  particularly  North  America  as  a  member  of  the  outlying 
insular  power  group )  are  viewed  by  the  Mackinder  of  1943  in  a  different 
light.  This  is  significant.  The  original  British  view  which  left  North 
America  seemingly  isolated  and  beyond  the  sphere  of  power  zones  di- 


218  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

rectly  linked  with  the  Heartland,  has  now  been  replaced  by  an  Anglo- 
American  world  view. 

Has  Mackinder  thus  silenced  his  critics?  Those  who  questioned  the 
validity  of  his  thesis  6  stressed  uniformly  the  pivotal  importance  of  the 
densely  populated  regions  of  the  marginal  coast  lands  or  rim  lands.  The 
overemphasis,  however,  on  either  inland  or  rim-land  location  neglects  the 
complementary  character  of  the  two,  as  well  as  their  constantly  changing 
values.  Mackinder  understood  these  dynamics  clearly.  He  re-examined 
and  revised  his  appraisal  of  the  relationship  between  interior  and  periph- 
eral; he  perceived  from  Britain  that  the  peripheral  felt,  more  than  ever, 
the  shadow  of  the  continental  land  mass  in  its  expansionist  movement. 
Thus  he  projected  a  new  vision  of  the  Heartland  in  its  relation  to  the 
surrounding  zones.  In  doing  so,  he  envisaged  the  geographic  link  be- 
tween the  Heartland  and  the  Anglo-American  world  in  a  new  light. 
From  Mercator  he  turned  to  the  globe.  Around  the  north  polar  regions 
he  hung  a  "mantle"  of  deserts  and  wildernesses.  From  the  Sahara  Desert, 
the  mantle  extends  to  the  deserts  of  Arabia,  Iran,  Tibet,  and  Mongolia. 
From  there  it  spreads  out  across  the  "wilderness  of  the  Lenaland"  to  the 
Laurentian  shield  of  Canada  and  to  the  subarid  belt  of  the  United  States. 

Thus  he  constructed  what  seems  to  be  a  new  "pivot  of  history";  a  zone 
including  both  the  Heartland  and  the  basin  of  North  Atlantic.  Thereby 
Mackinder  reveals  a  new  fulcrum  of  world  power,  and  a  new  relation- 
ship between  the  Heartland  and  the  outer  world.  The  enlarged  pivotal 
area  of  1943  is  made  apparent  by  drawing  a  great  circle  arc  from  the 
center  of  the  Yenisei  River  across  the  mid-ocean  to  the  center  of  the  Mis- 
sissippi valley.  The  arc  leads  across  the  bridgehead  of  France,  over  the 
stronghold  of  Britain— "a  Malta  on  a  grander  scale"— to  the  vast  arsenal 
of  the  eastern  and  central  United  States  and  Canada.  This  North 
American-British-French-U.S.S.R.  bloc  comprises  a  power  fulcrum  of  one 
billion  people.  It  neatly  balances  that  other  thousand  million  in  the  mon- 
soon lands  of  India  and  China.  "A  balanced  globe  of  human  beings.  And 
happy,  because  balanced  and  thus  free."  7 

THE  BALANCE-OF-POWER  FORMULA 

This  balance  was  too  neat  and  perfect  to  be  true.  The  power  bloc 
within  which  Communist  China  and  the  Soviet  Union  are  allied,  has 
upset  Mackinder's  balance,  if  it  ever  was  a  reality.  We  shall  not  deal 

6  See  especially  N.  J.  Spykman,  The  Geography  of  the  Peace  (New  York,  1944). 

7  Mackinder,  "The  Round  World  and  the  Winning  of  the  Peace,"  loc.  cit. 


THE  IMPACT  OF  LOCATION  219 

in  detail  with  Mackinder's  final  balance-of-power  vision,  a  world  divided 
into  two  equal  hemispheres  of  one  billion  human  beings  each,  because 
it  was  from  the  beginning  a  structure  built  upon  shifting  sand.  Like 
other  neat  balance-of-power  formulas,  it  did  not  work,  not  because  a 
North  American-British-French-U.S.S.R.  bloc  appears  utterly  unrealistic 
at  this  time,  but  because  one  cannot,  in  terms  of  geographic  realities 
and  of  human  and  natural  resources,  construe  a  balance-of-power  formula 
which  can  be  applied  permanently  to  the  world  relationship  of  one 
major  area,  such  as  the  Heartland.  The  relativity  of  power  relations  be- 
tween human  areas  was  demonstrated  clearly  in  the  history  of  Mac- 
kinder's own  thesis.  During  the  fifty  years  in  which  he  was  allowed  to 
watch  and  revise  his  Heartland  thesis,  new  pivot  areas  have  evolved 
and  still  others  are  due  to  emerge.  New  areas  and  their  peoples  have 
come  of  age,  and  will  continue  to  come  of  age.  New  lines  of  communi- 
cation will  transform  international  relations. 

The  revised  Heartland  concept  of  1943  wisely  acknowledged  a  signifi- 
cant geopolitical  fact  by  including  with  the  coast  land  of  Europe  the 
North  American  rim  lands  and  central  regions  in  the  enlarged  pivotal 
area.  Since  it  is  our  purpose  to  clarify  in  terms  of  relative  location  the 
relationship  between  North  America  and  the  Eurasian  continent  by  fol- 
lowing Mackinder's  changing  vision  of  this  relationship,  we  might  empha- 
size the  fact  that  his  enlightened  view  still  remained  a  view  through 
British  glasses.  Britain  is  the  vital  link  in  his  concept  of  the  "Mid-Ocean" 
as  the  main  artery  making  the  United  Nations  bloc  (without  China)  a 
life  force.  Does  he  not  try  to  prove  too  much?  Do  not  his  own  lessons  of 
a  phase  of  history  in  which  land  power  ( plus  land-based  air  power )  chal- 
lenges the  remnants  of  the  Victorian  age,  guide  us  to  additional  routes 
which  extend  from  North  America  to  the  Heartland? 


NEW  LINKS  BETWEEN  HEARTLAND,  NORTH  AMERICA 
AND  NORTHERN  ASIA 

These  routes  do  not  touch  Britain,  although  they  touch,  through  Can- 
ada, life  lines  of  the  British  Commonwealth  of  Nations.  Mackinder's 
latest  vision  pushes  the  Lenaland  and  with  it  the  whole  of  Soviet  Asia 
into  the  background.  This  seems  logical  if  one  views  the  Heartland  from 
the  British  Isles.  However,  a  view  of  the  Heartland  from  any  place  in 
North  America  exposes  the  fact  that  the  mid-ocean  avenue  is  by  no 
means  the  only  one  connecting  North  America  and  the  Heartland.  The 
established  sea  lanes  of  the  North  Atlantic  are  and  will  probably  remain 


220  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

the  cheapest  avenues;  but,  in  years  to  come,  traffic  will  mount  on  the 
new  highways  and  skyways  to  the  Heartland  and  to  Western  and  North- 
ern Europe  across  both  the  Alaska  and  the  Greenland-Iceland  bridges. 
While  we  are  aware  of  the  climatic  barriers  which  always  may  hamper 
an  American  and  Russian  expansion  northward  and  a  large-scale  col- 
onization and  land-utilization  of  their  Arctic  possessions,  we  can  not 
eliminate  the  northern  links  from  the  blueprint  of  a  new  world  view. 
These  links  are  represented  not  only  by  skyways  but  also  by  new  inland 
communications  and  by  sea  lanes,  opened  by  weather  stations,  planes, 
and  ice  breakers.8 

It  has  been  suggested  that  such  emphasis  on  the  frozen,  desolate  lands 
of  ice  and  snow  which  form  the  new  frontier  of  contact  between  the  Old 
and  the  New  World  is  unrealistic  because  "the  Polar  Mediterranean  and 
its  surrounding  territory  represent  the  greatest  inhospitable  area  on  the 
surface  of  the  globe."  9  Such  criticism  would  be  justified  were  it  directed 
only  at  the  loose  thinking  which  indeed  often  ignores  the  physical  ob- 
stacles to  large-scale  human  settlement  in  the  American  and  Russian  Far 
North.  However,  the  attempts  at  de-emphasizing  the  growing  significance 
of  these  regions  miss  their  target  when  it  comes  to  a  consideration  of 
not  only  (admittedly  limited)  agricultural  potentials  but  especially  the 
vast  mineral  resources  and,  above  all,  the  tremendous  timber  resources 
of  the  polar  regions;  the  latter  loom  even  larger  in  the  light  of  develop- 
ments in  the  field  of  wood  and  cellulose  technology. 

Of  greater  importance  in  the  evaluation  of  the  global  picture  of  the 
Arctic  regions  is  the  strategic  consideration.10  In  case  of  a  military  con- 
flict between  the  United  States  and  the  Soviet  Union,  it  is  obvious  that 
important  military  operations  would  take  place  north  of  50°  and  a  con- 
siderable portion,  and  possibly  a  decisive  one,  within  the  Arctic  Circle. 
To  emphasize  that  in  spite  of  man's  efforts  to  push  northward  every- 
where, digging  for  mineral  resources  in  the  eternally  frozen  soil  of  the 
tundra  and  even  growing  barley  beyond  the  timber  line,  the  Polar  ter- 
ritory remains  essentially  inhospitable  to  human  settlement,  is  beside  the 
point  when  it  comes  to  locating  the  areas  of  paramount  strategic  impor- 
tance on  the  world  map.  For  wars  are  not  necessarily  fought  and  decided 
in  densely  populated  regions,  as  is  shown  by  the  role  of  North  Africa 
and  New  Guinea  in  the  history  of  World  War  II.  Strategic  location  can, 
and  often  does,  outweigh  population  and  resources  in  determining  not 

8  See  pp.  246  ff. 

9  Spykman,  Geography  of  the  Peace,  pp.  56,  39. 

10  Ibid.,  pp.  43-45. 


THE  IMPACT  OF  LOCATION  221 

only  battle  sites  but  the  over-all  importance  of  a  region  in  a  global  pic- 
ture. It  goes  without  saying  that  the  factor  of  strategic  location  would 
loom  larger  than  ever  in  nuclear  warfare.  For  this  reason,  the  link  be- 
tween North  America  and  Europe  across  the  mid-ocean  avenue  is  par- 
alleled significantly  by  the  links  to  the  Heartland  across  the  Alaska  and 
the  Greenland-Iceland  bridges. 

Similarly,  it  would  be  mistaken  to  view  the  geographical  relationship 
between  the  Heartland  and  China  too  much  in  terms  of  sea  communica- 
tions. Of  growing  importance  are  the  new  inland  roads,  already  either 
in  operation  or  in  the  planning  state,  which  together  with  new  airways 
bring  the  Heartland  gradually  closer  to  China,11  whose  old  front  doors 
on  the  Pacific  coast,  in  Hongkong  and  Shanghai,  are  disintegrating.  One 
significant  achievement  in  this  development  was  claimed  in  the  Soviet 
Union  in  November,  1954,  when  Pravda  reported  the  completion  of  the 
easternmost  section  of  the  Baikal-Amur  railroad  from  Lake  Baikal  to  the 
Pacific  near  Khabarovsk.12  Equally  the  growing  net  of  Arctic  air  routes 
between  North  America  and  Japan  and  the  Asian  continent  de-emphasizes 
a  spatial  relationship  based  in  the  not-so-distant  past  entirely  on  the  link 
of  Pacific  sea  lanes. 

These  connections,  both  actual  and  potential,  disprove  any  construc- 
tion based  on  an  alleged  position  of  North  America  as  part  of  an  outer 
crescent  surrounding  the  Eurasian  land  mass  or,  as  Mackinder  postulated 
in  1943,  based  on  a  maritime  link  only,  leading  from  the  Heartland  across 
France  and  the  British  Isles  to  the  eastern  and  central  United  States  and 
Canada.  The  new  connecting  links  across  the  Arctic  Mediterranean  and 
its  surrounding  regions  emphasize  the  fallacy  of  any  world  view  focused 
on  an  alleged  geographic  isolation  of  the  United  States  within  the 
allegedly  secure  confines  of  an  equally  mystical  "Western  Hemisphere."  13 
But  they  also  stress  the  significance  of  the  Heartland  zone  itself.  The 
incessantly  growing  net  of  interior  lines  of  communication— railroads, 
highways,  inland  canals,  and  airways  across  its  skies— adds  consistently  to 
the  strength  of  a  Soviet  Union  endowed  with  the  geographic  advantage 
of  a  central  position  and  growing  interior  lines  of  transportation. 

Viewing  this  growing  land  power  from  a  Britain  whose  empire,  based 
on  the  control  of  the  sea,  he  saw  declining,  Mackinder  in  his  final  ap- 
praisal found  his  thesis  as  sound,  and  as  portentous,  as  ever;  for  "the 
Heartland— for  the  first  time  in  history  is  manned  by  a  garrison  sufficient 

11  Ibid.,  p.  42. 

12  New  York  Times,  November  21,  1954. 

13  See  pp.  258  ff. 


222  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

in  both  numbers  and  quality."  14  He  compared  the  Eurasian  land  mass, 
its  central  position  and  all  its  advantages  of  interior  lines  of  communica- 
tion connecting  it  with  the  regions  which  he  had  described  as  the  "inner 
crescent,"  with  the  exterior  lines  of  British  naval  power  "running  from 
Great  Britain  through  the  circumferential  highway  around  the  Eurasian 
rimlands."  15  The  comparison  did  not  favor  Britain.  The  Heartland  loomed 
larger  than  ever. 

It  looms  large  and  is  in  close  and  increasing  propinquity  to  the  north- 
ern borders  of  North  America,  a  propinquity  which  renders  useless,  be- 
cause unrealistic,  any  attempt  at  picturing  the  Western  Hemisphere  in  a 
state  of  remoteness  and  isolation  as  part  of  an  outer  crescent  surrounding 
the  Heartland.  As  a  glimpse  of  the  globe  or  any  world  map  not  inspired 
by  Mercator  makes  clear,  the  two  "mainlands"  almost  merge  in  their 
northern  expanses.  It  is  here  that  the  land  power  and  the  land-based  air 
power  of  the  North  American  nations  and  of  the  U.S.S.R.  are  now  maneu- 
vering for  positions  in  anticipation  of  a  possible  major  conflict. 

REASSESSMENT  OF  THE  POSITION  OF  RUSSIA  AND  U.S.S.R. 

Mackinder's  new  arrangement  of  the  political  map  of  the  world— the 
Heartland  itself,  the  marginal  lands  of  the  inner  crescent,  the  lands  of 
the  outer  crescent  beyond  that  of  the  peripheral  states— served  (as  we 
have  seen)  above  all  the  purpose  of  reassessing  in  geographical  terms 
the  position  of  the  Russian  empire  in  the  world  at  large;  in  political 
terms  this  reassessment  was  to  serve  as  an  eloquent  warning  to  the  West- 
ern world  aligned  with  British  sea  power.  It  recognized  as  the  signal 
geopolitical  development  of  the  young  twentieth  century  the  increasingly 
powerful  position  of  Russia  due  to  her  central  position  and  steadily  grow- 
ing communication  system  of  railroads,  highways,  and  inland  canals. 
These  interior  lines  of  communication  were  seen  as  a  rising  challenge  to 
powers  relying  on  sea  communication.  On  the  other  hand,  it  must  be 
realized  that  the  railroads  of  the  U.S.S.R.,  while  playing  the  major  role 
in  the  transportation  economy  of  the  country,  are  still  far  from  satisfac- 
tory,16 in  spite  of  the  fact  that  the  Soviet  regime  which  inherited  a  net- 
work of  36,300  miles  has  since  increased  the  railroad  mileage  to  about 
78,000  miles.  But  especially  in  Soviet  Asia,  the  railway  system  is  still 
skeletal  in  nature  and  the  supply  situation,  especially  from  a  military 


14  Foreign  Affairs,  July,  1953. 

15  Spykman,  Geography  of  the  Peace,  p.  40. 


16  T.  Shabad,  Geography  of  the  U.S.S.R.  (New  York,  1951),  pp.  83-88. 


THE  IMPACT  OF  LOCATION  223 

point  of  view,  of  the  far-flung  corners  of  the  empire— Central  Asia,  East- 
ern Siberia,  and  the  Maritime  Provinces— can  be  described  as  crucial 17 
(cf.  Fig.  15-2,  p.  478). 

THE  RIM  LANDS 

In  this  comparison  of  geographical  foundations  of  land  power  and  sea 
power  we  are  taught  to  distingush  between  interior  lands  inaccessible  to 
navigation,  and  coast  lands  or,  as  they  have  also  been  called,  marginal 
lands  or  rim  lands,  which  are  accessible  to  the  shipmen,  sailing  from 
beach  to  beach  and  harbor  to  harbor  round  the  west,  south,  and  east 
coasts  of  the  Old  World,  and  sailing  up  its  navigable  rivers.18  Nicholas  J. 
Spykman  has  justly  criticized  Mackinder  for  oversimplifying  the  land 
power  versus  sea  power  conflict.  The  historical  alignment,  he  pointed  out, 
has  always  been  in  terms  of  some  member  nations  of  the  European  rim 
land  with  Great  Britain  against  Russia  in  alliance  with  other  members  of 
the  rim  land;  or  it  has  been  a  conflict  between  Great  Britain  and  Russia 
together  against  a  rim  land  power  which,  as  for  instance  France  or  Ger- 
many, dared  to  gamble  for  the  domination  of  the  continent.  Hence  Spyk- 
man's  formula  in  critique  of  Mackinder's:  "Who  controls  the  rimland, 
rules  Eurasia;  who  rules  Eurasia  controls  the  destinies  of  the  world."  19 

There  are  a  number  of  significant  geographical  factors  which  justify 
the  attempt  to  classify,  in  terms  of  political  geography,  the  marginal  lands 
(or  rim  lands)  as  distinctive  units  differentiated  in  many  ways  from  the 
interior  lands  that  are  inaccessible  to  sea  power  and  form  the  basis  of 
the  Heartland.  These  regions  have  in  common  three  major  character- 
istics distinguishing  them  from  the  interior  lands. 

( 1 )  With  the  exception  of  the  Heartland's  north,  where  west  winds 
carry  a  considerable  amount  of  rainfall  across  the  plains  as  far  inland  as 
the  Altai  Mountains,  the  inland  areas  are  at  a  disadvantage  in  regard 
to  water  supply  as  compared  with  the  marginal  lands  which  can  count 
on  reliable  rainfall  sufficient  for  agriculture. 

(2)  The  marginal  lands  are  centers  of  population  density.  It  should 
also  be  noted  that,  within  the  Soviet  Heartland  region,  the  greatest  con- 
centration of  population,  agricultural  and  industrial  concentration,  and 
power  potential  is  in  the  western  regions  of  the  inland  area,  close  to  the 
marginal  lands. 

17  W.  G.  East,  "How  Strong  Is  the  Heartland?"  Foreign  Affairs  (1950),  pp.  78-93, 
87. 

18  Cf.  C.  B.  Fawcett,  "Marginal  and  Interior  Lands  of  the  Old  World,"  in  Weigert- 
Stefansson-Harrison,  op.  cit.,  pp.  91-103. 

19  Spykman,  Geography  of  the  Peace,  p.  40  ff. 


224  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

(3)  The  marginal  lands,  in  terms  of  political  organization,  lack  the. 
political  unification  and  centralization  of  power  which  characterizes  the 
Heartland  power.  They  are  broken  up  into  a  number  of  more  or  less  in- 
dependent national  units  which,  however,  strive  in  the  face  of  aggression 
threats  toward  new  forms  of  supranational  unification.20 

Thus  we  are  led  to  that  crucial  cradle-of-conflict  zone  which  extends 
along  the  western  frontier  of  the  Soviet  Union  and,  continuing  westward, 
forms  in  an  irregular  peninsula  the  center  of  the  so-called  continent  of 
Europe.  As  seen  from  Moscow,  or  London,  or  Washington,  the  nations  of 
this  broad  rim-land  zone,  while  politically  lacking  uniformity  and  unifica- 
tion, share  certain  basic  advantages  due  to  their  geographical  rim-land 
position.  To  a  large  extent  these  account  for  the  concentration  and  growth 
of  their  population  and  their  agricultural  and  industrial  wealth.  They 
are  the  rim  lands  the  control  of  which,  it  was  claimed,  endows  the  ruling 
power  with  control  over  Eurasia  and,  consequently,  of  the  world.  Mar- 
ginal as  these  lands  are  to  the  Heartland,  they  must  be  viewed  in  their 
role  of  actual  and  potential  extensions  of  the  Heartland  itself.  We  have 
seen  how  Mackinder  developed  his  thesis  along  strategic  considerations; 
sea  power  and  land  power  required  new  appraisals  based  on  geographic 
facts  and  new  lines  of  communication.  Thus  the  strategic  Heartland  be- 
came the  region  to  which,  under  modern  conditions,  sea  power  can  be 
refused  access  by  a  locally  dominant  land  power. 

In  the  light  of  this  strategic  concept,  it  becomes  evident  that  certain 
marginal  areas  are  needed  to  achieve  the  security  objective  of  the  Heart- 
land, namely,  to  extend  its  perimeter  to  a  line  which  would  assure  the 
Heartland  of  the  exclusion  of  sea  power.  We  shall  note  immediately  that 
emphasis  on  the  land  power-sea  power  conflict  meant  even  before  the 
advent  of  air  power  a  gross  oversimplification,  as  it  is  the  accessibility  to 
both  sea  and  land  and  the  power  deriving  from  it  which  gives  the  mar- 
ginal regions  growing  importance.  In  the  second  half  of  the  twentieth 
century,  the  impact  of  air  power  makes  a  new  appraisal  of  the  marginal 
lands  mandatory,  in  their  relationship  to  the  Heartland  as  well  as  to  other 
areas. 

THE  HEARTLAND  AND  EASTERN  EUROPE 

In  attempting  to  define  the  major  strategic  areas  forming  the  marginal 
lands  to  the  west  of  the  Heartland  and  having  enough  in  common  to  be 
treated  as  entities,  the  political  divide  created  by  the  Iron  Curtain  makes 
it  necessary  to  distinguish  between  the  regions  of  Eastern  and  Central 

20  Fawcett,  "Marginal  and  Interior  Lands  of  the  Old  World,"  loc.  clt. 


THE  IMPACT  OF  LOCATION 


225 


i  L L 

2 1 

3  


Fig.  8-3.  Marginal  Lands  to  the  West  of  the  Heartland:  (1)  U.S.S.R.;  (2)  satellites; 

(3)  marginal  lands. 


Europe  and  the  rest  of  Europe  (Fig.  8-3).  As  was  stressed  previously,  a 
major  distinguishing  factor  between  the  lands  of  the  interior  and  the  mar- 
ginal regions  to  the  west  of  them  is  a  negative  one  and  one  strictly  related 
to  political  geography:  whereas  in  the  middle  of  the  twentieth  century  the 
Heartland  interior  is  a  politically  integrated  unit  fully  controlled  by  the 
Kremlin,  the  countries  of  Eastern  and  Central  Europe  are  characterized 
by  the  existence  of  politically  conflicting  structures,  with  both  East  and 
West  attempting  to  mold  them  into  a  unified  sphere.  In  political  terms, 
this  region  includes  Germany,  Poland,  Czechoslovakia,  Rumania,  Austria, 
Hungary,  Bulgaria,  Albania,  and  on  their  periphery,  Finland,  Yugoslavia, 
and  Greece.  It  goes  without  saying  that  in  this  pivotal  area  of  centuries- 
old  clashes  between  the  East  and  the  West  any  attempt  at  visualizing  this 
area  as  a  political  unit  of  some  broader  meaning  defies  proper  geographi- 
cal definition.  Its  typical  state  is  one  of  fluctuation  and  transition;  its 
human  geography  was  rewritten  many  times  in  history  as  a  result  of  wars 
and  migrations  sweeping  westward  and  eastward.  Yet,  if  only  we  apply 
the  term  marginal  area  in  a  broad  sense,  we  can  appreciate  it  as  a  large- 
space  concept  complementary  to  the  interior  lands  of  the  Heartland. 


226  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

It  would  be  futile  to  try  to  define  the  location  of  the  thin  boundary  line 
which  separates  the  Western  extension  of  the  Heartland  from  the  eastern 
border  regions  of  the  marginal  lands.  Therefore,  it  is  immaterial  to  deter- 
mine whether  certain  highly  important  regions  in  this  broad  frontier  zone 
between  Heartland  and  rim  lands  belong  to  either  category.  What  mat- 
ters is  the  fact  that  in  spite  of  the  impressive  pace  of  U.S.S.R.  develop- 
ment in  what  the  Russians  refer  to  as  "the  eastern  regions,"  the  Volga- 
Ural  region  and  Soviet  Asia  beyond  it,21  European  Russia  and  certain 
areas  adjacent  to  it  are  indispensable  to  the  Heartland  power.  Regardless 
of  whether  the  Baku  oilfields,  the  Rumanian  oilfields,  the  breadbasket 
and  industries  of  the  Ukraine,  or  the  coal  mines  and  industries  in  Upper 
Silesia  form  an  annex  of  the  Heartland  area  or  an  outpost  of  the  marginal 
region,  their  location  is  such  that  they  are  extremely  vulnerable  to  attack 
from  without,  especially  from  bases  located  in  the  "perimeter  of  defense" 
belt,  in  Britain,  Scandinavia,  the  Western  European  mainland,  North 
Africa,  or  the  Middle  East.  The  result  is  that  the  top-heavy  concentration 
of  population,  agricultural  and  industrial  assets  of  the  Soviet  empire  along 
the  western  and  most  vulnerable  border  regions  of  the  Heartland  reduces 
the  intrinsic  value  of  the  Heartland  as  a  whole  and  of  the  power  connota- 
tions it  implies. 

The  concentration  of  economic  power  and  power  potentials  in  the  west- 
ern fringe  areas  of  the  Heartland,  which  is  still,  in  the  second  half  of  the 
twentieth  century,  a  major  characteristic  of  the  Heartland  power,  has  thus 
fully  confirmed  Mackinder's  thesis  that  he  "who  rules  East  Europe  com- 
mands the  Heartland."  At  the  same  time,  we  must  not  lose  sight  of  the 
marchlands  along  the  eastern  border  of  the  Heartland.  As  in  the  case  of 
Eastern  Europe,  to  focus  attention  on  the  Heartland  per  se,  with  its  cen- 
tral position  in  Eurasia,  its  physical  inaccessibility  from  the  oceans,  its 
seeming  security  from  attack  due  to  the  natural  bastion  provided  by  the 
frozen  waters  of  the  Arctic  and  the  mountain  ranges  and  steppes  of  Cen- 
tral Asia,  leads  to  an  underestimation  of  the  rim  lands  in  the  east  which 
play  a  significant  role  in  linking  the  Heartland  with  the  rest  of  the  world. 
The  conquests  of  Alexander  the  Great  and  of  the  Arabs  remind  us  of  the 
role  of  the  marginal  areas  of  Southwest  Asia  in  historical  efforts  aimed  at 
controlling  the  Heartland.  Even  more  important  was  the  challenge  to  the 
Heartland  by  the  empire  of  the  Mongols.  Its  nucleus  of  power  located  in 
the  steppes  of  Mongolia,  it  broadened  its  basis  to  include,  in  the  thir- 
teenth century,  China  proper.22  In  reverse,  and  as  seen  from  Moscow,  the 

21  East,  "How  Strong  Is  the  Heartland?"  loc.  cit.,  p.  90. 

22  Ibid.,  pp.  83,  84. 


THE  IMPACT  OF  LOCATION  227 

same  marchlands,  like  those  in  Eastern  Europe,  provide  stepping  stones 
for  the  expansion  of  the  Heartland  power  itself.  Lenin's  prediction  that 
the  road  to  Paris  leads  through  China  and  India  still  rings  ominously.  The 
slow  growth  of  railroads  in  Siberia  and  toward  the  Pacific  coast  as  well 
as  in  Central  Asia  links  the  Heartland  more  and  more  with  marchlands  of 
great  strategic  portent,  even  more  strategic  in  as  much  as  the  correspond- 
ing railroad  system  developed  by  China  and  linking  its  mainland  with  the 
outer  regions  remained  (as,  for  instance,  in  the  case  of  Sinkiang)  utterly 
weak  and  vulnerable. 


THE  INTERRELATIONSHIP  OF  HEARTLAND  AND 
MARGINAL  LANDS 

It  must,  therefore,  be  concluded  that  the  study  of  location  which  the 
investigation  of  the  Heartland  and  its  physical  qualities  entails,  while  con- 
tributing greatly  to  the  understanding  of  its  strength,  is  not  enough  and 
is  even  misleading  if  it  amounts  to  a  preoccupation  with  the  Heartland 
concept.  In  order  to  arrive  at  a  balanced  view,  the  study  must  be  extended 
to  include  the  marginal  lands  along  all  of  the  frontiers  of  the  Heartland. 
In  these  regions  where  the  Soviet  sphere  of  expansion  and  influence  is  met 
and  challenged  by  the  "perimeter  of  defense"  23  organized  by  the  Free 
World,  it  is  frequently  the  concentration  of  populations  and  the  wealth  of 
resources,  rather  than  geographical  position  by  itself  which  accounts  for 
their  pivotal  role.  The  combination  of  power  based  on  the  Heartland's 
central  area  and  greatly  increased  control  over  vital  parts  of  the  marginal 
belt,  not  the  central  nucleus  of  the  Heartland  alone,  would  represent  a 
unit  which  could  challenge  with  a  high  degree  of  success  the  power  posi- 
tion of  the  rest  of  the  world.  However,  it  must  be  realized  that  the  impact 
of  time  and  change,  due  to  progress  in  technological  achievement,  is  such 
that  this  formula  holds  good  but  in  general  terms  and  must  be  re-examined 
whenever  makers  of  policy  or  planners  of  strategy  put  it  to  test  at  a  given 
time. 

B.    Strategic  Implications  of  the  Location  of  Marginal  Seas 

and  Narrow  Waterways 

Marginal  seas  and  narrow  waterways  occupy  today,  as  in  past  history, 
a  highly  important  position  in  the  struggle  for  powers  and  rank  high 
among  the  geographical  foundations  of  political  and  military  power.  In 

23  See  page  272  ff. 


228  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

the  present  conflict  between  the  Soviet  orbit  and  the  West,  the  evaluation 
of  the  opposing  power  systems  makes  it  mandatory  to  understand  the 
effect  of  the  locational  factors  of  marginal  seas  and  narrow  waterways  on 
the  respective  powers— their  geography  granting  decisive  qualities  of 
strength  and  weakness,  qualities  which  have  molded  historical  geography 
and  which  define  political  geography  today.  A  glimpse  at  the  map  of 
water  bodies  does  not  always  disclose  easily  power  and  control  factors  of 
the  nations  competing  in  these  areas.  The  locational  impact  of  these  water 
bodies  on  the  countries  bordering  them  does  not  reveal  itself  on  the  map 
as  clearly  as  is  the  case  in  regard  to  the  factors  of  location  which  define 
the  areal  situation  of  a  country  and  its  relations  to  other  countries  across 
land  borders.  Their  role  becomes  apparent  only  if  projected  against  larger 
space  configurations.  Both  the  importance  of  the  location  concepts  of  these 
water  bodies  and  the  complicating  factors  which  render  difficult  the  ap- 
praisal of  their  geopolitical  values  make  it  appear  advisable  to  discuss  the 
major  marginal  seas  and  narrow  waterways  in  some  regional  detail. 

Stretching  around  the  vast  littoral  of  the  Eurasian  land  mass,  from 
Spitsbergen  to  the  Kuriles,  is  a  chain  of  islands  and  archipelagoes,  some 
delimiting,  others  within  a  series  of  marginal  seas  and  narrow  waterways. 
These  control  vital  sea  communications  of  the  world  and  are  likely  to  be 
pivotal  areas  in  any  conflict  between  the  two  power  blocs  that  is  not  im- 
mediately decided  by  atomic-thermonuclear  weapons  of  air  power.  The 
marginal  seas  are  peculiar  to  the  Eurasian  continent.  The  only  similar 
instance  of  enclosed  sea  in  the  North  and  South  American  continent  is 
that  of  the  Caribbean  Sea,  which  is  defined  by  the  Bahamas  and  the 
Antilles. 

The  significance  of  these  marginal  seas  and  the  narrow  straits  within 
them  cannot  be  overemphasized.  So  long  as  intermediate  bases  are  main- 
tained by  the  Free  World  in  the  coastal  regions  of  Eurasia,  they  function 
as  a  cordon  sanitaire  around  the  expanse  of  the  Soviet  domain.  Once  this 
line  of  sea  communications  is  breached  by  Soviet  penetration,  the  entire 
peripheral  strategy  of  the  Free  World  would  be  endangered.  The  sea  com- 
munications of  the  Free  World  are  secure  only  if  the  seas  through  which 
they  pass  and  the  narrow  straits  on  which  they  converge  are  secure.  The 
potential  threat  of  such  penetration  must  not  be  seen  in  the  possible  rise 
of  the  Heartland  power  to  the  stature  of  a  maritime  power  able  to  chal- 
lenge Anglo-American  naval  supremacy,  for  geography  is  prohibitive  to 
such  development.  Rather  the  threat  is  against  the  sea  lanes  from  aircraft 
based  in  the  Heartland  itself  and  in  satellite  rim  lands.  Nicholas  J.  Spyk- 
man's  observation  still  holds  true:  "there  is  no  geopolitical  area  in  the 


THE  IMPACT  OF  LOCATION  229 

world  that  has  been  more  profoundly  affected  by  the  development  of  air 
power  than  this  one  of  the  marginal  seas."  24  The  development  of  air 
power  has  not  reduced  the  importance  of  these  seas  and  communications 
focal  points,  but  it  has  made  them  more  difficult  to  defend.  Besides  the 
defenses  located  in  the  immediate  vicinity  of  the  waterway,  it  is  now 
necessary  to  establish  bases  hundreds  of  miles  away.  A  case  in  point  is  the 
entire  Caribbean,  which  is  now  a  part  of  the  defensive  perimeter  of  the 
Panama  Canal. 

In  the  period  between  the  sixteenth  and  twentieth  centuries  it  was  pos- 
sible to  keep  enemy  ships  and  troops  outside  artillery  range  of  a  narrow 
waterway.  This  is  no  longer  true,  since  aircraft  can  now  make  the  water- 
way untenable  even  to  the  nation  which  controls  it.  Although  that  nation 
remains  in  a  position  to  prevent  enemy  traffic  from  passing  through  it, 
hostile  aircraft  can  render  it  too  costly  to  send  friendly  ships  through  the 
channel.  Early  in  World  War  II  Britain  did  not  dare  to  send  its  ships 
through  the  Suez  Canal  because  of  the  threat  of  German  air  power.  Such 
an  air  threat  necessitates  the  maintenance  of  distant  air  bases  to  provide 
adequate  aircraft  interception.  A  discussion  of  these  waterways  and  their 
distinguishing  geographic  characteristics  enables  us  to  see  in  true  per- 
spective the  marginal  problems  of  the  Heartland  power  itself  and  equally 
those  of  the  nations  in  the  perimeter  of  defense  zones. 

THE  GEOGRAPHICAL  PATTERN 

If  a  strip  map  were  constructed  extending  from  the  northwestern  North 
American  coastline  and  the  eastern  Asiatic  coastal  area  it  would  reveal 
a  succession  of  marginal  seas  defined  by  an  almost  interminable  chain  of 
islands  and  archipelagoes  ( Fig.  8-4 ) .  This  is  particularly  true  of  the  imme- 
diate continental  margin,  where  from  the  Arctic  Circle  to  the  Equator, 
and  beyond,  there  is  a  regular  repetition  of  the  same  simple  geographical 
pattern.  The  continental  mainland  is  separated  everywhere  from  the  open 
oceans  by  a  succession  of  partly  enclosed  seas,  each  protected  and  easily 
defended  on  the  Pacific  side  by  curving  peninsular  and  island  barriers. 
These  loop-like  barriers,  swinging  toward  the  mainland  at  either  extrem- 
ity, not  only  define  and  separate  the  marginal  seas  but  lead  to  a  sequence 
of  straits  and  narrows  that  have  great  strategic  significance. 

Beginning  in  the  Alaska  peninsula,  and  continuing  through  the  Aleu- 
tians, the  first  arc  ties  in  to  the  shore  of  Kamchatka,  shutting  in  the  Bering 
Sea  and  covering  the  most  accessible  entries  into  the  Yukon  and  Anadyr 

24  Spykman,  Geography  of  the  Peace,  p.  54. 


Fig.  8-4.  Succession  of  Marginal  and  Enclosed  Seas — from  North  America  to  the 

Indian  Ocean. 

230 


THE  IMPACT  OF  LOCATION  231 

valleys.  Near  the  Alaskan  end  the  United  States  has  a  strong  naval  base 
at  Dutch  Harbor,  while  the  corresponding  Russian  base  is  at  Petropav- 
lovsk  on  Kamchatka. 

The  second  unit  in  this  pattern  begins  with  the  Kamchatka  Peninsula 
and  is  continued  without  a  break  by  the  Kurile  Islands,  which  follow  a 
running  curve  and  then  tie  in  with  the  northeastern  extremity  of  Hok- 
kaido. The  last  of  these  islands,  Paramushiro,  is  a  northern  Gibraltar  in 
sight  of  Kamchatka.  These  islands  are  controlled  by  the  U.S.S.R.  and 
make  of  the  Sea  of  Okhotsk  a  virtual  Russian  lake,  controlling  the  north- 
ern access  to  the  Amur  basin. 

The  third  arc  begins  with  Sakhalin,  which  is  separated  by  less  than 
twenty  miles  from  the  continental  coast,  and  extends  southward  for  over 
seven  hundred  miles  to  the  northwestern  tip  of  Hokkaido.  From  this  point 
Japan  itself  forms  the  outer  arc,  which  at  its  southwestern  extremity  ap- 
proaches within  sixty  miles  of  the  Korean  coast.  Enclosed  within  this  arc 
is  the  Sea  of  Japan.  Mid-way  along  the  continental  shore  is  the  Soviet 
naval  base  of  Vladivostok,  guarding  the  eastern  terminus  of  the  Trans- 
Siberian  railroad  and  projecting  Soviet  naval  power  toward  the  chain  of 
Japanese  islands. 

The  fourth  geographical  unit  can  be  traced  from  the  Korean  peninsula 
through  Kyushu  ( part  of  Japan  proper )  and  the  Ryukyu  chain  which  ties 
in  to  the  island  of  Formosa.  The  enclosed  China  Sea  has  a  secondary  inner 
basin,  the  Yellow  Sea,  and  two  innermost  recesses,  the  Gulfs  of  Chihli  and 
Liaotung,  behind  the  Kwantung  Peninsula.  This  whole  outer  arc,  nearly 
two  thousand  miles  long,  faces  toward  the  entrances  to  Manchuria,  the 
North  China  Plain,  and  the  Yangtze  Basin.  Within  this  arc  on  the  main- 
land is  the  port  city  and  naval  base  of  Shanghai.  In  the  southern  entry  to 
the  China  Sea  the  Formosa  Strait  is  narrowed  further  by  the  Pescadores. 
They  are  located  within  the  United  States  perimeter  of  defense  as  defined 
in  January,  1955. 

The  fifth  repetition  of  this  geographical  pattern  is  drawn  on  a  larger 
scale  than  its  northern  counterparts.  Beginning  with  Formosa,  an  outer 
protective  barrier  runs  through  the  Bataan  Islands  (part  of  the  Philip- 
pines), Luzon,  Mindoro,  Palawan,  Northern  and  Western  Borneo,  Billiton, 
Banka,  and  eastern  Sumatra.  The  last  swings  in  toward  Malaya  and  thus 
completes  the  enclosure  of  the  South  China  Sea  while  defining  its  southern 
entry  through  Malacca  Strait.  Singapore,  Bangkok,  Hanoi  and  Hong  Kong 
all  lie  within  this  barrier.  The  area  is  honeycombed  with  shallows  and 
treacherous  waters  which  confine  ships  to  well-defined  sea  lanes. 

Thereafter,  this  configuration  of  marginal  seas  is  lost  in  the  Indian 


INDIAN         OCEAN 


0         100     ZOO     300     400     500  Ml 

l 1  I 1  1=1 


0  200        400         600   Km 


<^\\  f       TIMOR 


m. 


Fig.  8-5.  The  South  China  Sea. 


232 


THE  IMPACT  OF  LOCATION  233 

Ocean  (unless  one  considers  the  Andaman  and  Nicobar  Islands  chain  as 
sufficient  to  define  the  contours  of  a  marginal  sea ) ,  only  to  reappear  in  a 
different  pattern  in  the  Middle  East  and  Western  Europe,  in  the  Persian 
Gulf,  the  Red  Sea,  the  Mediterranean  Sea,  North  Sea,  Baltic  Sea,  White 
Sea  and  the  Barents  Sea.  With  the  exception  of  the  Red  Sea  and  the 
Persian  Gulf  all  of  these  seas  wash  the  shores  of  Heartland— or  Heartland 
controlled— marginal  territory;  the  North  Sea  in  this  sense  is  seen  as  form- 
ing a  unit  with  the  Soviet-dominated  Baltic  Sea.  As  marginal  seas  they 
have  immediate  importance  in  any  effort  by  the  Soviet  Union  to  gain  clear 
access  to  the  open  Atlantic,  the  Mediterranean,  and  the  Indian  Ocean. 
Such  an  effort  would  presuppose  control,  by  the  Heartland  power,  of  the 
narrow  straits  which  must  be  passed  to  reach  the  open  sea. 

Scattered  along  the  chain  of  islands  and  archipelagoes  in  the  Pacific 
and  dotting  the  system  of  marginal  seas  in  Europe  and  the  Middle  East 
are  those  focal  points  between  land  masses  which  provide  egress  from  the 
interior  or  marginal  seas.  These  straits  and  channels  are  not  as  numerous, 
however,  as  one  might  expect.  In  many  instances  where  they  do  exist  sea 
traffic  is  impeded  or  strictly  channeled  by  the  nature  of  treacherous 
shoals.  A  graphic  illustration  of  the  importance  of  deep  straits  occurred 
after  the  Battle  of  the  Java  Sea  in  1942.  All  the  deep  exits  from  this  sea 
were  guarded  by  Japanese  vessels,  which  sank  or  captured  most  of  the 
Allied  ships.  The  shallower  craft  were  able  to  make  the  passage  between 
Java  and  Bali  Island  (Bali  Strait),  and  were  able  to  escape  the  lone  Japa- 
nese guard.  But  the  larger  ships  that  tried  to  escape  through  the  Sunda 
Strait  (between  Sumatra  and  Java)  and  Lombok  Strait  (between  the 
islands  of  Bali  and  Lombok  in  the  Indonesian  archipelago)  encountered 
armed  forces  too  large  to  evade  or  conquer.25 

Most  of  the  strategic  waterways— the  narrow  passages— of  the  world  can 
be  divided  into  two  general  classes:  those  which  are  maritime  highways 
between  two  of  the  great  oceans;  and  those  giving  access  to  enclosed  or 
semienclosed  seas.  In  the  first  group  are: 

(1)  The  Mediterranean  system,  including  the  Strait  of  Gibraltar,  the 
Sicilian  Straits,  the  Suez  Canal,  the  Red  Sea,  and  the  Strait  of  Bab-el- 
Mandeb.  This  is  the  vastly  important  water  passage  through  the  Eurafri- 
can  land  mass  to  India  and  Southeast  Asia— vitally  important  in  the 
peripheral  strategy  of  the  Free  World. 

(2)  The  Panama  Canal,  connecting  the  Atlantic  and  Pacific  Oceans, 
with  its  antechamber,  the  Caribbean  Sea  and  the  passages  which  connect 

25  E.  G.  Mears,  Pacific  Ocean  Handbook  (San  Francisco,  1944),  p.  43. 


234  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

the  latter  with  the  Atlantic  Ocean.  Of  these,  the  Windward  Passage  is  of 
first  importance. 

(3)  The  waterways  linking  the  Indian  and  Pacific  Oceans  (Fig.  8-5). 
These  include  the  Strait  of  Malacca,  Sunda  Strait,  and  Singapore  Strait, 
which  provide  access  from  the  Indian  Ocean  to  the  South  China  Sea;  San 
Bernardino  Strait  and  Surigao  Strait,  which  connect  the  South  China  Sea 
with  the  Pacific;  Lombok  and  Macassar  Straits,  which  connect  the  Indian 
Ocean  with  the  Java  and  Celebes  Seas;  and  Torres  Strait,  which  connects 
the  Arafura  Sea  to  the  Coral  Sea.26 

In  the  second  category— passages  providing  access  to  enclosed  seas  or  to 
seas  which  for  all  practical  purposes  are  enclosed— are  the  following: 

(1)  The  Turkish  Straits,  including  the  Dardanelles,  the  Sea  of  Mar- 
mara, and  the  Bosporus,  which  provide  access  to  the  Black  Sea  from  the 
Mediterranean. 

(2)  The  Straits  at  the  entrance  to  the  Baltic  Sea.  These  are  the  Kattegat 
and  Skagerrak,  The  Sound,  and  the  Great  Belt.  The  Kiel  Canal  is  an  alter- 
nate entrance  to  the  Baltic  Sea. 

( 3 )  St.  George's  Channel  and  the  Irish  Channel,  which  are  the  southern 
and  northern  entrances  to  the  Irish  Sea. 

(4)  The  entrances  to  the  Sea  of  Japan.  These  include  the  Tartary  Strait, 
La  Perouse  Strait,  Tsugaru  Strait,  Tsushima  and  Shimonoseki  Straits. 

(5)  The  Strait  of  Ormuz,  giving  access  to  the  Persian  Gulf  from  the 
Indian  Ocean.27 

Perhaps  still  a  third  group  of  vital  waterways  can  be  distinguished  in 
the  narrow  channels  which  pass  between  insular  areas  and  the  mainland. 
Certainly  the  most  important  of  these  is  the  English  Channel.  In  addition, 
the  Strait  of  Formosa  connects  the  East  and  South  China  Seas,  Hainan 
Strait  separates  the  island  from  the  mainland,  Palk  Strait  separates  Ceylon 
from  the  southern  tip  of  the  Indian  mainland,  and  the  Straits  of  Messina 
lie  between  Sicily  and  the  Italian  toe.  The  Strait  of  Bonifacio,  between 
Sardinia  and  Corsica,  and  the  Strait  of  Otranto,  between  Albania  and 
Italy,  have  a  secondary  importance. 

For  the  past  century  it  has  been  Britain  which  has  dominated  the  sea 
lanes  and  sea  communications,  but  it  must  be  stressed  that,  in  the  spring 
of  1956,  the  British  naval  and  air  base  position  between  Aden  and  Aus- 
tralia appeared  to  be  crumbling:  Bombay  passed  from  British  control  in 

26  G.  F.  Eliot,  "Strategic  Waterways,"  United  Nations  World  (September,  1947), 
pp.  30-35. 

27  Ibid. 


THE  IMPACT  OF  LOCATION  235 

1950;  the  government  of  Ceylon  requested  in  1956  an  early  evacuation  of 
the  British  base  at  Trincolamee;  its  air  bases  in  Malaya  are  threatened  by 
Communist  infiltration;  and  Britain's  control  of  Aden  is  under  pressure 
both  from  within  the  colony  and  from  Egypt,  Saudi  Arabia,  and  Yemen. 
Britain  had  established  its  domination  of  the  sea  lanes  by  seizing  all  but 
three  of  the  strategic  gateways  or  bottlenecks  between  the  oceans.  Of  the 
remaining  three,  that  at  Panama  remained  in  the  friendly  hands  of  the 
United  States,  while  two  others  in  the  Indonesian  archipelago— then  held 
by  the  Netherlands— were  also  under  friendly  control.  Controlling  the 
strategic  sea  lanes  in  this  manner,  "not  a  ton  of  interocean  shipping  could 
move  on  the  earth  without  going  past  British  or  United  States  points  of 
naval  control."  28  A  globe-girdling  chain  of  strategic  naval  bases  was  con- 
structed to  safeguard  these  points  of  control.  Although  constructed  or 
acquired  in  days  of  the  sailing  vessels,  the  foresight  in  their  selection 
made  them  equally  valuable  once  steam  and  oil-powered  vessels  sup- 
planted sailing  ships.  As  already  noted,  the  most  severe  challenge  to  their 
usefulness  and  the  usefulness  of  the  narrow  waterways  is  to  be  seen  in  the 
ability  of  air  power  to  neutralize  them. 

Today  these  narrow  straits  are  still  under  the  dominant  control  of 
Anglo-American  naval  power  or  of  smaller  nations  friendly  to,  or  even 
dependent  on,  that  power.  A  discussion  of  these  waterways  will  point  this 
up  although  the  precarious  position  of  the  British  base  net  and  the  under- 
mining effect  of  this  weakness  on  the  security  of  the  United  States  and 
the  free  world  as  a  whole  must  be  kept  in  mind. 

THE  SEA  OF  JAPAN 

Of  the  entrances  to  the  Sea  of  Japan  (Fig.  8-6)  all  except  the  Strait  of 
Tartary  and  La  Perouse  Strait  are  wholly  controlled,  on  both  shores,  by 
American  forces  occupying  Japan  and  South  Korea.  The  northern  shore  of 
La  Perouse  Strait  is  formed  by  the  Russian  island  of  Sakhalin.  The  Tartar 
Strait  is  wholly  Russian,  but  ice  closes  it  during  a  great  part  of  the  year. 
Despite  the  U.S.S.R.  naval  base  at  Vladivostok  the  Sea  of  Japan  is  effec- 
tively counterbalanced  by  the  United  States  so  long  as  occupation  forces 
continue  to  remain  in  Japan  and  South  Korea.  Whether,  and  if  so,  to  what 
extent,  submarine  warfare  and  the  mining  of  port  entrances  would  in  a 
war  necessitate  a  reappraisal  of  this  situation  is  in  the  realm  of  specu- 
lation. 

28  G.  T.  Renner  and  associates,  Global  Geography  (New  York,  1944),  p.  618. 


I.I    I    |....»WIWIIII«W»^WW 


m 

mm 

:•:■:■:■:•:  •■:-.*.; 
:■:•:*:*:■:  ••:•:•:■ 


iiCHINA 


Tokyo    ^ 


Cftina      Sea 


Fig.  8-6.  Sea  of  Japan. 


236 


THE  IMPACT  OF  LOCATION  237 

FROM  INDIA  TO  THE  PACIFIC 

The  waterways  linking  the  Indian  and  Pacific  Oceans  are  still  domi- 
nated by  British  naval  power  at  Singapore.  In  conjunction  with  United 
States  naval  forces  in  the  Philippines  the  entire  Southeast  Asian  series  of 
narrow  waterways  is  effectively  dominated.  The  only  immediate  threat  to 
Singapore  is  a  Communist  drive  down  the  Malayan  peninsula  comparable 
to  the  successful  Japanese  thrust  in  the  Second  World  War.  The  network 
of  sea  communications  in  this  area  is  second  only  in  importance  to  that 
of  the  Mediterranean.  Not  only  is  it  the  vital  hub  of  communications  be- 
tween the  Indian  and  Pacific  Oceans,  but  also  it  controls  communications 
extending  north  through  the  Formosa  Strait  to  the  Japanese  Islands.  The 
access  of  the  maritime  powers  to  all  of  Southeast  Asia  and  a  considerable 
part  of  the  Far  East  thus  depends  on  friendly  control  of  this  sea  communi- 
cations hub.  The  Bering  Strait  to  the  north,  separating  Alaska  and  eastern 
Siberia,  is  difficult  of  access  both  by  sea  and  from  the  interior. 

THE  PANAMA  CANAL  AND  CARIBBEAN  AREA 

This  area  is  wholly  controlled  by  the  United  States  (cf.  Fig.  3-6,  p. 
72).  The  Caribbean  Sea  is  the  key  to  the  Panama  defenses  and  includes 
three  independent  republics  and  possessions  of  the  United  States,  Britain, 
France,  and  the  Netherlands.  As  a  practical  matter,  however,  it  is  an 
American  lake,  dominated  by  sea  and  air  power.  The  outer  zone  of  sec- 
ondary bases  stretches  from  Exuma  in  the  Bahamas  to  Antigua  and  St. 
Lucia  in  the  Lesser  Antilles,  both  leased  bases.  The  inner  zone  of  main 
defense  covers  an  arc  reaching  from  Guantanamo  Bay  on  Cuba  in  the 
west  to  San  Juan  in  the  north  and  Trinidad  in  the  southeast.  On  the  west- 
ern approaches,  leased  bases  in  the  Galapagos  Islands  of  Ecuador  protect 
the  canal  from  a  distance  of  a  thousand  miles  away.  The  canal  is  vital  in 
the  East- West  communications  of  the  entire  free  world,  and  as  such  is  the 
only  narrow  waterway  of  great  strategic  importance  in  the  North  and 
South  American  continents.  The  rest  of  the  world's  strategic  waterways 
are  found  in  the  marginal  seas  ringing  the  Eurasian  land  mass. 

THE  BALTIC  SEA 

Following  the  long  coast  line  of  the  U.S.S.R.,  from  the  westernmost  of 
its  Arctic  seas,  the  Barents  Sea,  and  its  southern  annex,  the  White  Sea 
which  has  become  increasingly  important  as  outlet  of  the  Baltic-White 


-% 


J.RF 


,□  m  >i 


Cfr. 

C OCEAN 


NORTH 

ATLANTIC 

OCEAN 


RljGEN 
I  ROSTOCK  .>&>      SWINEMUNDE 
-:    SMAR  •      "    EAST    %^~>J^^X^        -^A 

7  STETTI^i  KOLBERG     POLAND 


3v  C"KALININORA 


immfm 


Fig.  8-7.  The  Baltic  Arena  and  Its  String  of  Soviet  Military  Bases:  ( 1 )  Soviet  bloc  nations 
(Porkkala  returned  to  Finland  1956);  (2)  neutral;  (3)  NATO  bloc. 


238 


THE  IMPACT  OF  LOCATION  239 

Sea  inland  waterway,  we  reach  the  Baltic  Sea,  Russia's  window  toward 
Scandinavia  and  the  Atlantic  (Fig.  8-7).  Slowly  but  systematically,  the 
Soviet  Union  has  increased  its  direct  control  of  the  Baltic  littoral  which 
had  been  for  a  long  time  limited  to  the  easternmost  section  of  the  Gulf 
of  Finland.  Ice-bound  half  of  the  year,  the  old  Russian  zone  seemed 
too  weak  to  assure  the  safety  of  Leningrad,  the  Soviet  Union's  second 
city.  The  Baltic  States  were  incorporated  in  1940.  With  their  annex- 
ation, the  Soviet  Union  organized  new  seaports  which  are  more  favor- 
ably located  than  is  Leningrad's  naval  base,  Kronstadt,  which  is  ice- 
bound for  five  to  six  months:  Tallinn,  the  main  port  of  Estonia,  is 
practically  ice-free;  the  important  port  of  Riga  in  Latvia  is  icebound 
for  about  three  months,  whereas  the  naval  base  of  Libau  is  relatively 
ice-free.  Farther  south,  the  U.S.S.R.  extended  her  Baltic  power  posi- 
tion through  control  of  Memel  in  Lithuania  and  the  port  city  of  Kalin- 
ingrad, the  former  Konigsberg,  which  is  ice-free  most  of  the  year.  In 
satellite  Poland,  the  twin  ports  of  what,  after  World  War  I,  formed 
the  Free  City  of  Danzig  and  of  Gdynia,  as  well  as  Szczecin  (Stettin), 
not  threatened  by  ice,  are  the  natural  outlets  of  the  Vistula  and  Oder 
basins  for  the  agricultural  and  industrial  products  of  Poland,  the  western 
Ukraine,  and  Silesia.  In  1955,  the  Soviet  Union's  grip  around  the  Baltic 
included  the  coastline  of  satellite  East  Germany  with  its  naval  stations  on 
the  island  of  Riigen  and  at  the  port  of  Rostock.  Its  flanking  expansion 
along  the  Baltic  littoral  ends  in  sight  of  the  West  German  port  of  Liibeck. 
This  extension  of  Soviet  Union  control  since  the  end  of  World  War  II 
has  greatly  improved  its  over-all  defensive  position  as  well  as  its  po- 
tential role  as  an  aggressor  in  the  Baltic  arena.  On  the  other  hand,  the 
strength  of  NATO  prevents  further  expansion  and  bars  the  Soviet  Union 
from  turning  the  Baltic  Sea  into  a  Russian  lake  from  which  its  naval 
power,  especially  its  submarines,  could  penetrate  into  the  Atlantic.  West 
Germany  controls  the  ports  of  Liibeck  and  Kiel  on  the  Kiel  Canal  which, 
in  its  length  of  fifty-three  miles,  cuts  through  Schleswig-Holstein  and  en- 
ters the  Elbe  river,  fifteen  miles  east  of  Cuxhaven.  Denmark,  the  natural 
goal  of  a  Russian  attempt  to  gain  full  control  of  the  Baltic  Sea  and  access 
to  the  Atlantic,  still  controls,  through  land  fortifications,  the  strategically 
important  island  of  Bornholm,  and  through  mine  fields,  The  Sound  and 
the  Belts.  Sweden,  in  its  important  outlet  to  the  North  Sea,  the  naval  base 
and  port  of  Goteborg,  shares  with  Denmark  in  the  defense  of  the  Kattegat. 
Sweden  is  not  as  exposed  a  Baltic  Power  as  is  Denmark.  Its  bases  in 
Stockholm,  Karlskrona,  and  on  the  island  of  Gotland  are  a  strong  protec- 


c 
c 

IS 


4) 

H 
06 

■ 

00 

o 

— 


_Nrx 


1- 

p 

g             £ 

; 

i°n 

1     ac 

i 

m 

o 

°m 

10 

O 

o 

" 

o 

o 

o  i 

o 

* 

i' 

to 

O 

o 

o 

CM 

o 

O 

i 

o 

oiL 

1 

o 

i 

/L 


240 


THE  IMPACT  OF  LOCATION  241 

tion  of  its  southern  lands  and  have  served  as  an  effective  deterrent  to  a 
challenge  of  Sweden's  neutrality.  Finland,  on  the  other  hand,  in  spite  of 
the  boundary  changes  effected  after  the  Russo-Finnish  war,  is  in  a  pre- 
carious position  because  of  its  close  proximity  to  the  Soviet  Union's  life- 
center  of  Leningrad.  Its  Aland  islands  which  control  the  entrance  to  the 
Gulf  of  Bothnia  have  been  neutralized.  In  conclusion,  we  find  the  Baltic 
arena  a  strategic  area  of  great  significance  both  to  the  Soviet  orbit  and  the 
Free  World.  Seen  from  the  standpoint  of  Soviet  Union  security,  the  Baltic 
defense  line  protects  the  vital  agricultural  and  industrial  concentrations 
between  Leningrad,  Moscow,  and  the  eastern  Ukraine  and  the  increas- 
ingly important  mining  districts  of  Upper  Silesia.  In  terms  of  aggression, 
the  U.S.S.R.  position  along  the  Baltic  coast  could  be  seen  as  a  stepping 
stone  for  Russian  expansion  into  the  Atlantic,  with  the  consequent  threat 
of  dangerous  submarine  warfare  against  Allied  shipping.  Conversely,  the 
location  of  NATO  strength  in  its  littoral  member  states  and  the  strong 
position  of  Sweden  produce  a  balance  of  power  which  halts  further  ex- 
pansion by  the  U.S.S.R.  and  helps  to  maintain  peace  because  the  Free 
World  occupies  strategically  favorable  positions  from  which,  in  retaliation 
to  aggressive  moves  by  the  Soviet  Union,  air  blows  or  even  an  invasion 
could  be  started  against  vital  industrial  centers  and  communications  lines 
in  the  European  expanses  of  the  Soviet  Union. 

THE  MEDITERRANEAN  NETWORK 

The  western  entrance  to  the  Mediterranean  (Fig.  8-8)  is  commanded 
by  the  Gibraltar  fortress,  its  British  rule  being  vainly  challenged  by  Spain. 
The  narrow  waist  is  dominated  by  the  British  fortress-island  of  Malta,  and 
to  some  extent  by  the  French  base  at  Bizerte  in  Tunisia  and  the  American 
air  base  at  Wheelus  Field  at  Tripoli.  Sicily  and  other  neighboring  Italian 
islands  are  de-neutralized  under  the  Italian  peace  treaty.  The  most  critical 
control  point  in  the  Mediterranean  vital  passageway  is  the  Suez  Canal.29 
The  concession  of  the  joint-stock  company  which  operates  the  canal  does 
not  expire  until  1968,  but  since  1954  the  canal  is  no  longer  under  British 
control.30  A  possible  alternative  control  point  for  the  eastern  Mediterra- 
nean is  the  British  island  of  Cyprus  and  naval  installations  in  the  Isken- 
deron  area  of  southeastern  Turkey.  However,  the  control  over  the  last 
British-ruled  bastion  in  the  Middle  East,  Cyprus,  appeared  to  be  seriously 

29  A.  Siegfried,  "The  Suez:  International  Roadway,"  Foreign  Affairs  (1953),  pp. 
605-618. 

30  See  pp.  639,  640. 


242  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

threatened  in  late  1955  by  the  mounting  hostility  of  400,000  Cypriotes  of 
Greek  descent,  who  were  fighting  for  "self  determination".  Other  narrow 
waterways  of  strategic  value  in  this  network  are  the  Turkish  Straits,  the 
Strait  of  Otranto,  the  Strait  of  Messina,  and  the  Strait  of  Bonifacio.  The 
latter  two  are  not  of  critical  importance,  but  are  available  as  convenient 
alternate  ship  routes. 

However,  such  listing  of  the  ramparts  that  guard  the  Mediterranean 
Sea  would  be  misleading  if  we  lost  sight  of  the  fact  that  the  Mediterranean 
in  its  true  power  connotations,  and  as  a  "pivot  of  peace  and  war,"  31  must 
be  looked  upon  as  a  continuous  waterway  made  up  of  two  unequal  parts, 
which  until  1869  functioned  separately— the  Mediterranean  proper  and 
the  Red  Sea— tenuously  linked  at  the  isthmus  of  Suez.32  It  should  be  noted 
that  the  loss  of  Egypt  as  kingpin  of  the  Middle  East  defense  position  has 
accentuated  the  critical  defense  position  of  the  Western  powers  in  the 
Middle  East  area  as  a  whole,  which  is  in  sharp  contrast  to  their  firmly 
established  security  system  in  the  Mediterranean  arena  itself. 


33 


THE  "GEOGRAPHICAL  BLOCKADE"  OF  THE  HEARTLAND  POWER 

The  control  of  the  sea  communications  throughout  the  maritime  world 
and  the  network  of  intermediate  bases  counterbalance  the  power  concen- 
tration in  the  Soviet-dominated  Eurasian  land  mass.34  We  have  stressed 
before  that  with  only  one  or  two  exceptions  the  most  vital  narrow  water- 
ways are  controlled  by  Anglo-American  naval  power.  This  naval  domi- 
nance extends  to  most  of  the  marginal  seas  as  well.  The  immediate 
advantage  to  the  Free  World  in  this  pattern  of  political  geography  is  the 
complete  accessibility  by  way  of  sea  communications  to  the  land  area 
dominated  by  the  Soviet  Union.  In  contrast  to  the  Eurasian  land  mass, 
the  shores  of  the  North  and  South  American  continents  fall  into  the  sea 
without  a  pattern  of  marginal  seas  or  insular  ramparts,  which  fact  accounts 
for  the  vastly  superior  defense  position  of  the  American  nations.  Geog- 
raphy endows  with  great  advantages  powers  whose  naval  strength,  sup- 
ported by  air  bases,  controls  the  marginal  seas  and  narrow  passageways, 
as  long  as  this  control  is  not  challenged  successfully  by  naval  and  air 
power  based  on  the  Eurasian  Heartland  or  rim  lands  under  its  control. 

31 W.  G.  East,  "The  Mediterranean:  Pivot  of  Peace  and  War,"  Foreign  Affairs 
(1953),  pp.  619-633. 

32  Ibid. 

33  W.  G.  East,  "The  Mediterranean:  Pivot  of  Peace  and  War,"  loc.  cit.,  pp.  631-633; 
see  especially  the  observations  on  the  alternative  of  a  British  defense-in-depth  system 
in  and  around  the  Indian  Ocean. 

s*  See  p.  214  ff. 


THE  IMPACT  OF  LOCATION  243 

This  observation  leads  to  the  conclusion,  borne  out  by  history,  that  the 
Heartland  power,  even  if  succeeding  in  the  establishment  of  a  firm  strong- 
hold over  the  Eurasian  marginal  lands,  will  try  to  extend  its  perimeter  of 
defense— or  aggression— to  include  the  marginal  seas  and  narrow  water- 
ways off  its  shores.  In  its  urge  toward  the  open  seas,35  the  Soviet  Union, 
as  formerly  Russia,  meets  with  formidable  barriers:  the  Soviet  Baltic  lake 
is  bottled  by  the  Skagerrak  and  the  Kattegat  ( cf.  Fig.  8-7 ) ;  her  Black  Sea 
outlet  to  warm  waters  is  choked  by  the  Turkish  Straits;  the  Bering  and 
Okhotsk  Seas  are  fogbound  and  icebound  a  great  part  of  the  year;  the  Sea 
of  Japan  is  subject  to  American  naval  power  in  Japanese  bases;  and  the 
succession  of  Anglo-American  naval  bases  along  the  whole  of  the  insular 
rampart  to  Singapore  would  serve  to  nullify  potential  Soviet  naval  power 
ranging  from  Tsingtao,  Shanghai,  Vladivostok,  and  Petropavlovsk. 

If  one  considers  a  possible  break-out  from  this  "geographical  blockade," 
with  the  factors  of  geography  foremost  in  mind,  the  two  most  likely  areas 
are  the  Baltic  and  Black  Seas.  The  former  brings  to  the  U.S.S.R.  most  of 
her  imports,  while  the  latter  carries  most  of  her  exports  to  world  markets. 
In  both  situations  the  Soviet  Union  is  confronted  with  a  narrow  waterway 
which  is  subject  to  Anglo-American  naval  control.  The  acquisition,  by  the 
Soviet  Union,  of  the  Finnish  coast  beyond  Viborg,  her  annexation  of  the 
Baltic  states  of  Latvia,  Estonia,  and  Lithuania  and  also  of  a  strip  of  East 
Prussia  which  includes  Kaliningrad,  are  evidence  that  the  Baltic  is  to 
become,  if  it  is  not  already,  something  of  a  Russian  lake,  its  security 
threatened,  however,  by  air  power  from  the  ring  of  bases  which  surround 
it.  Furthermore,  a  concentration  of  Soviet  naval  power  in  the  Baltic  serves 
no  great  interest  of  the  Soviet  Union  unless  it  can  reach  out  beyond  the 
Kiel  Canal,  The  Sound,  and  the  Great  Belt  to  the  North  Sea  and  beyond. 

A  similar  joining  of  rival  naval  forces  would  occur  in  the  Aegean  if  the 
U.S.S.R.  were  ever  successful  in  breaking  out  from  the  Black  Sea  through 
the  narrow  Bosporus  into  the  Sea  of  Marmara,  and  from  there  through  the 
winding  channel  of  the  Dardanelles  into  the  Aegean  Sea.  Anglo-American 
naval  power  would  appear  to  be  highly  sensitive  to  Russian  intrusion  on 
the  eastern  Mediterranean  sea  lanes,  not  to  mention  the  neutralization  of 
Turkey  that  would  result  from  such  a  successful  breaching  of  this  geo- 
graphical barrier.  Hanson  N.  Baldwin  stated  the  case  clearly  in  saying 
that  "geography  is  the  Russian  Navy's  undoing"  and  that,  even  if  the 
Dardanelles  were  to  fall  to  Communist  armies,  the  maze  of  islands  in  the 

35  See  the  comprehensive  account  by  R.  J.  Kerner,  "The  Soviet  Union  as  a  Sea 
Power,"  in  Weigert-Stefansson-Harrison,  op.  cit.,  pp.  104-122;  see  also,  F.  Uligh,  Jr., 
"The  Threat  of  the  Soviet  Navy,"  Foreign  Affairs  (1952),  pp.  444-455. 


244  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

Aegean  and  the  closed  waters  of  the  Mediterranean  would  make  a  sortie 
by  Russian  surface  ships  or  submarines  a  desperate  adventure.36 

If  one  views  the  Baltic  and  Black  Seas  and  their  narrow  passageways 
through  the  glass  of  the  Heartland  power  that  is  trying  to  render  the  land 
mass  itself  and  the  marginal  lands  it  dominates  secure  against  attack  from 
without,  it  is  evident  that  they  play  as  important  a  part  in  the  security 
system  of  the  Heartland  complex  as  do  the  marginal  lands  adjacent  to  its 
borders.  These  marginal  areas,  as  well  as  the  western  territories  of  the 
Heartland,  are  accessible  at  both  ends  from  the  sea.  Any  power  equipped 
with  the  ships  and  with  air  cover  to  penetrate  into  the  Baltic  and  Black 
seas  would  create  a  serious  threat  to  the  security  of  the  Heartland-rim 
land  structure  as  a  whole.  Clearly  these  marginal  seas  and  their  pathways 
loom  large  in  the  strategy  of  both  the  Soviet  Union  and  the  West.  The  case 
histories  of  the  Black  Sea  and  of  the  Baltic  Sea,  as  well  as  those  of  the 
other  marginal  seas  discussed,  offer  significant  evidence  that  the  appraisal 
of  any  security  and  power  position  remains  incomplete  unless  the  margi- 
nal seas,  and  their  passageways,  be  given  proper  consideration.  As  a  foot- 
note to  this  general  appraisal,  it  should  be  added  that  the  strong  emphasis 
on  submarine  construction  in  the  Soviet  Union— which,  in  1955,  was  re- 
ported to  have  three  hundred  submarines  in  service— is  clearly  its  attempt 
at  partial  solution  of  the  geographical  problems  of  the  Heartland-rim  land 
structure.  In  an  appraisal  of  the  geographical  barriers  which  obstruct  the 
Soviet  Navy,  Hanson  W.  Baldwin  concluded  in  1955  37  that  its  construc- 
tion program 

.  .  .  will  reach  really  dangerous  proportions  only  if  two  or  more  of  the  following 
developments  occur:  (1)  If  Soviet  long-range  planes  with  an  operational  radius 
of  at  least  1,000  miles  and  a  capability  for  effective  attack  upon  shipping  learn 
to  co-ordinate  their  operations  with  Soviet  submarines; 

(2)  If  Russia  acquires  new  open- water  naval,  submarine  and  air  bases  on  the 
coasts  of  Western  Europe  by  land  conquests  ( as  Germany  did  in  World  War  II ) ; 

(3)  If  the  industrial  facilities  of  Soviet  Siberia  are  strengthened  so  greatly  as 
to  be  capable  of  the  self-sufficient  support  of  a  very  much  more  powerful  Far 
Eastern  Fleet; 

(4)  If  a  breach  in  the  Western  Pacific  island  chain  is  achieved  by  Communist 
conquest  or  political  action  so  as  to  provide  Soviet  Russia  with  a  warm-water 
port  fronting  on  the  open  Pacific. 

The  Achilles'  heel  of  Soviet  Russia's  deep-sea  power  today  is  her  naval  base 
complex.  Her  most  important  and  best  bases  are  bottled  up  in  narrow  seas;  the 
few  that  give  access  to  the  open  ocean  are  subject  to  the  vagaries  of  Arctic 
weather  and  are  vulnerable  to  atomic  or  conventional  bombing  attack  by  land- 
based  or  ship-based  aircraft. 

36  "The  Soviet  Navy,"  Foreign  Affairs  (1955),  pp.  587-604  (590,  591). 
■«  Uiid.,  p.  604. 


THE  IMPACT  OF  LOCATION  245 

Soviet  Russia's  naval  might  cannot  be  dismissed  as  a  factor  in  her  present 
global  power.  But  it  is  not  a  major  factor.  Her  submarine  strength  and  in  par- 
ticular her  minelaying  capabilities  deserve  increasing  respect.  But  it  is  still  true 
today  as  it  was  in  the  days  of  the  Tsars  that  if  Russia  is  to  challenge  the  United 
States  or  Great  Britain  for  primacy  upon  the  high  seas  she  must,  besides 
strengthening  her  maritime  power  with  increased  export  trade,  acquire  warm- 
water  ports  fronting  upon  the  open  oceans  of  the  world  and  expand  her  ship- 
building industry  and  the  vast  industrial  complex  to  support  it. 


NARROW  MARINE  STRAITS  IN  THE  ANTARCTIC 

Our  discussion  of  the  strategically  significant  narrow  passages  would 
be  incomplete  without  mentioning  the  increasingly  important  role  of 
the  Drake  Passage  between  South  America  and  Palmer  Peninsula  (Fig. 
8-9),  ominously  important  because  of  the  vital  role  this  passage  would 
assume  if  in  a  future  conflict  passage  through  the  Panama  Canal  or 
the  Suez  Canal,  or  through  both  of  them,  would  be  barred.  In  such  a 
case  ships  would  have  to  plough  the  Antarctic  Seas  on  their  way  from 
the  Pacific  to  the  Atlantic,  or  on  their  way  from  the  Atlantic  to  the 
Indian  Ocean.  The  political  geography  of  the  Antarctic  sphere  of  in- 
terest has  come  into  the  picture  very  late,38  but  the  possible  blocking 
of  the  passages  through  the  Suez  and  Panama  Canals  has  made  the 
Drake  Passage,  between  Tierra  del  Fuego  and  the  Falkland  Islands 
to  the  north  and  the  outer  reaches  of  Antarctica  to  the  south,  a  po- 
tentially decisive  strategic  area.  Many  nations  are  now  competing  for 
sovereignty  rights  in  the  Antarctic  arena.  Argentina  has  established 
stations  at  both  ends  of  the  Drake  Passage.  Competing  with  Argentina 
are  Chile,  Great  Britain  (which,  in  1908,  set  up  her  Falkland  Islands 
Dependencies),  and  the  United  States,  as  well  as  other  nations  with 
more  or  less  specific  claims.  Significant  battles  for  the  control  of  these 
Antarctic  waters  were  fought  in  World  Wars  I  and  II  when  in  both  wars 
the  Germans  succeeded  in  playing  havoc  with  Allied  shipping  in  southern 
waters.  Forewarned  by  the  experiences  of  the  two  wars,  Argentina,  Chile, 
and  Britain  have  established  themselves  in  the  Palmer  Peninsula  area  and 
are  competing  in  their  sovereignty  claims.  The  United  States  in  1955  com- 
pleted a  non-military  Antarctic  exploratory  mission  (the  U.S.S.  Atka 
expedition)  and  has  good  ground  for  sovereignty  claims  of  its  own  in  the 
Palmer  Peninsula.  The  Soviet  Union,  in  an  ominous  move  late  in  1955, 
announced  plans  to  establish  three  bases  near  the  South  Pole.  These  plans 
could  be  interpreted  as  the  possible  beginning  of  a  double  flanking  of 

38  L.  Martin,  "The  Antarctic  Sphere  of  Interest,"  in  Weigert-Stefansson-Harrison, 
op.  cit.,  pp.  65-73  (65). 


246 


THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 


Fig.  8-9.  Drake  Passage  in  Relation  to  the  Panama  and  Suez  Canals. 

Australia  and  New  Zealand  by  the  Soviet  Union.  It  has  been  argued  39 
that  a  considerable  Communist  air  power  might  gain  a  foothold  in  Indo- 
nesia in  the  next  ten  to  fifteen  years,  unless  the  influence  of  the  Free  World 
prevails.  If  the  Soviet  Union  would  establish  Antarctic  air  bases,  Australia 
and  New  Zealand  would  be  vulnerable  from  the  West,  too.  Forty  nations 
will  take  part  in  the  Geophysical  Year,  1957-58,  with  the  United  States' 
expedition  under  the  command  of  Rear  Admiral  Richard  E.  Byrd  as  a 
major  participant.  Time  will  tell  whether  and  in  what  respects  the  objec- 
tives in  the  fields  of  pure  science  will  be  overshadowed  by  strategic, 
political,  and  economic  developments  in  the  vast  and  empty  Antarctic 
arena. 

LOCATIONAL  FACTORS  OF  THE  ARCTIC:  THE 
ARCTIC  MEDITERRANEAN 

The  Arctic  Ocean  is  in  actuality  a  part  of  the  Atlantic  Ocean  whose 
littoral  includes  the  land  masses  of  the  Northern  Hemisphere.  It  has  been 
rightly  termed  the  Polar  Mediterranean.  When  Vilhjalmur  Stefansson 


39  New  York  Times,  November  20,  1955. 


THE  IMPACT  OF  LOCATION  247 

coined  this  phrase  in  1922,  he  defined  it  in  terms  which,  if  examined  in 
retrospect,  appear  to  be  visionary: 


40 


A  map  giving  one  view  of  the  northern  half  of  the  northern  world  shows  that 
the  so-called  Arctic  Ocean  is  really  a  Mediterranean  sea  like  those  which  sepa- 
rate Europe  from  Africa  or  North  America  from  South  America.  Because  of  its 
smallness,  we  would  do  well  to  go  back  to  an  Elizabethan  custom  and  call  it  not 
the  Arctic  Ocean  but  the  Polar  Sea  or  Polar  Mediterranean.  The  map  shows  that 
most  of  the  land  in  the  world  is  in  the  Northern  Hemisphere,  that  the  Polar  Sea 
is  like  a  hub  from  which  the  continents  radiate  like  the  spokes  of  a  wheel.  The 
white  patch  shows  that  the  part  of  the  Polar  Sea  never  yet  navigated  by  ships 
is  small  when  compared  to  the  surrounding  land  masses.  In  the  coming  air  age, 
the.  .  .  Arctic  will  be  like  an  open  park  in  the  center  of  the  uninhabited  city  of 
the  world,  and  the  air  voyagers  will  cross  it  like  taxi  riders  crossing  a  park.  Then 
will  the  Arctic  islands  become  valuable,  first  as  way  stations  and  later  because 
of  their  intrinsic  value— minerals,  grazing,  fisheries  .  .  . 

The  Arctic  Mediterranean  is  an  excellent  example  of  an  area  in  which 
technological  progress,  especially  in  aviation,  has  caused  far-reaching 
changes  which  make  imperative  a  reorientation  and  a  new  evaluation  of 
locational  factors  of  the  area.  Because  of  these  aspects  of  location,  a  review 
of  some  of  them  is  necessary  in  order  to  appraise  the  new  role  of  the  Arc- 
tic in  the  relationships  of  the  northern  powers. 

As  the  air  age  has  developed,  more  and  more  attention  has  been  focused 
upon  the  Arctic,  for  over  the  Arctic  pass  the  great  circle  routes  connecting 
the  United  States  and  Canada  and  the  Far  East  in  one  direction  and  in  the 
other  direction  linking  the  United  States  with  Northwestern  Europe.  The 
great  circle  is  the  flyer's  short  cut,  for  the  arc  of  a  great  circle  is  the  short- 
est distance  between  two  points  on  a  sphere. 

In  laying  out  a  great-circle  course  between  New  York  and  Moscow,  or 
between  Chicago  and  Peiping,  the  great-circle  routes  pass  over  the  Arctic 
(Fig.  8-10).  Until  1954,  in  most  cases,  the  implications  were  more 
significant  for  military  planning  than  in  the  field  of  commercial  avi- 
ation. Prior  to  1954  the  airlines  of  commerce  followed  the  longer  courses 
of  trans-oceanic  flight  in  an  effort  to  serve  an  optimum  of  population 
centers.  Civil  aviation  succeeded  late  in  1954  in  making  the  Arctic 
short  cut  to  Europe  a  regular  airline  route.  The  Scandinavian  Airlines 
initiated  scheduled  flights  from  Los  Angeles  to  Copenhagen,  with  stops 
at  Winnipeg,  Canada,  and  Sondre  Stromfjord,  Greenland.  The  distance 
measures  5,085  nautical,  or  about  5,800  statute  miles,  being  465  nautical 
miles  ( 535  statute  miles )  shorter  than  the  trip  by  way  of  New  York.  The 
timetable  calls  for  the  eastbound  polar  flight  to  take  about  twenty-four 

40  "The  Arctic  as  an  Air  Route  of  the  Future,"  National  Geographic  Magazine 
(1922),  p.  205  ff. 


s 
« 

e 


s 

o 

u 

< 


33 


« 

— ■ 

S 
- 

3 
O 


O 

■ 

00 

u 


248 


THE  IMPACT  OF  LOCATION  249 

hours,  a  saving  of  three  or  four  hours  over  the  conventional  route.  This 
regular  "over  the  top"  service  is  likely  to  be  the  forerunner  of  many 
more  such  airline  routes  and  it  is  reported  that  the  Scandinavian  Airlines 
has  blueprinted  a  transpolar  service  from  Oslo  to  Tokyo  that  would  cut 
the  run  from  fifty-three  hours  to  twenty-four.  This  example  shows  the 
impact  of  new  transpolar  air  routes  in  civil  aviation  upon  peacetime 
relations  of  the  nations  which  these  routes  are  to  link  so  much  more 
speedily  and,  as  a  result,  more  firmly.  The  new  links  between  California 
and  the  Scandinavian  countries  offer  a  good  illustration  of  the  radical 
changes  in  the  locational  relationships  of  "distant"  countries  as  the  result 
of  the  opening  of  new  skyways  above  the  Polar  regions. 

In  terms  of  locational  relations  of  the  great  powers  we  are  still  strug- 
gling to  grasp  the  changes  which  Polar  aviation  has  caused  in  the  loca- 
tional relationships  of  the  powers  of  the  West  and  East,  by  turning  the 
Arctic  Mediterranean  and  its  frozen  lands  into  a  pivot  area  and  strategic 
center.  This  concept  reveals  itself  best  on  a  north-polar  version  of  a  great- 
circle  chart.  With  its  great-circle  projections,  this  is  the  kind  of  map  the 
aviator  needs.  To  him  the  idea  of  our  Polar  Mediterranean  is  familiar.  To 
many  navigators  and  to  those  who  have  grown  up  in  the  shadow  of  the 
Mercator  projection  (with  the  poles  at  infinity)  this  vision  has  appeared 
strange  and  almost  inconceivable  not  so  long  ago.  In  terms  of  flying,  the 
grouping  of  the  nations  around  the  Polar  Mediterranean  reveals  the  ele- 
mentary truth  that  the  direct  route  between  any  of  these  nations  is  in  some 
northerly  direction;  on  the  cylindrical  Mercator  world  map  (with  the 
poles  lost  in  its  open  ends)  the  logical  flight  direction  is  seemingly  east 
or  west. 

It  is  over  this  Arctic  Mediterranean  that  air  strikes  upon  the  United 
States  and  retaliatory  raids  may  be  expected.  Even  the  exchange  of  guided 
missiles  would  take  place  over  the  Arctic  great-circle  routes,  not  only  be- 
cause these  offer  the  shortest  distance,  but  also  because  the  Arctic  area  is 
difficult  to  defend.41 

The  air  distance  from  New  York  to  Moscow  is  4,675  miles  by  way  of 
the  Arctic.  The  air  distance  from  San  Francisco  to  Peiping  by  way  of  the 
Arctic  is  6,600  miles,  3,000  miles  shorter  than  the  trans-Pacific  route.  These 
distances  appear  formidable,  but  this  is  not  the  distance  aircraft  would 
have  to  travel  in  the  event  of  an  East- West  war,  for  the  Arctic  Mediterra- 
nean is  being  ringed  with  bases  by  both  the  United  States  and  the  Soviet 
Union  (see  pp.  249  ff. ).  The  distance  over  the  Arctic  from  the  important 

41  J.  W.  Watson,  "Canada:  Power  Vacuum,  or  Pivot  Area?"  in  Weigert-Stefansson- 
Harrison,  op.  cit.,  pp.  40-60. 


250  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

United  States  base  at  Thule,  Greenland,  is  only  2,752  miles  to  Moscow, 
whereas  the  nearest  Soviet  base  at  Rudolf  Island,  one  of  the  Franz  Joseph 
groups,  is  3,800  miles  distant  from  New  York  City. 

This  is  a  reflection  of  the  greater  depth  of  the  United  States  from  the 
pole  as  compared  with  the  U.S.S.R.  The  core  area  of  the  Soviet  Union  is 
centered  along  the  55th  parallel.  It  is  15  degrees  closer  to  the  pole  than  the 
United  States  core  area,  which  is  centered  along  the  40th  parallel.  How- 
ever, it  would  be  fallacious  to  conclude  that  this  locational  relationship 
gives  North  America  a  strategic  advantage  over  the  Soviet  Union.  It  must 
be  realized  that  the  polar  ice  pack,  and  the  advance  positions  it  offers  to 
all  Arctic  powers,  puts  the  weapon-bearers  of  our  time  in  closest  prox- 
imity. 

The  polar  ice  pack,  although  it  develops  areas  of  open  water,  is  a  vast 
ice  landing  field;  a  field  which  also  contains  floating  ice  islands  more 
stable  than  the  pack  of  ice  itself.  The  first  of  these  ice  floes  was  reported 
by  the  U.S.  Air  Force  in  1946  and  named  T-l;  subsequently,  two  more 
were  located  in  1950  (T-2  and  T-3).  According  to  Soviet  claims  their 
airmen  had  noted  earlier  the  presence  of  these  ice  islands  and  estab- 
lished the  identification  of  certain  other  floes  in  the  sector  claimed  by 
the  U.S.S.R.  as  "North  Pole  One,  Two,"  and  so  on. 

These  islands  may  last  for  years  and  perhaps  even  for  centuries. 
However,  the  islands  discovered  by  the  U.S.S.R.  are  not  as  large  as  the 
ones  reported  by  the  United  States  Air  Force,  and  the  Soviet  Union  has 
had  to  make  the  best  of  ice  floes  a  mile  or  so  in  length  and  perhaps  ten  feet 
thick.  Both  the  United  States  and  the  Soviet  Union  use  the  ice  islands  as 
bases  of  operations  for  their  Arctic  research.42 

Another  vast  ice  landing  strip  is  the  Greenland  Ice  Cap  which  is  also 
a  possible  refueling  base;  uninhabited,  with  the  exception  of  radar  sta- 
tions in  the  vicinity  of  Thule,  the  ice  cap  presents  a  good  location  for 
caching  fuel.  With  the  exception  of  the  crevassed  edges  of  the  Greenland 
Ice  Cap  aircraft  landings  can  be  made  almost  anywhere,  especially  on  its 
ice  lakes.  The  strategic  importance  of  this  uninhabitable  section  of  the 
world  cannot  go  unrecognized  and  the  long-term  strategic  implications 
are  equally  significant  both  for  offense  and  defense.  This  was  demon- 
strated during  World  War  II  when  the  Germans  maintained  a  series  of 
weather  stations  along  the  Greenland  Coast.  These  weather  observation 
stations  in  the  North  Atlantic  "weather  factory"  for  Northwestern  Europe 

42  The  dangerous  overlapping  of  American  and  U.S.S.R.  ice  island  zones  is  illus- 
trated by  newspaper  reports  in  February,  1955,  according  to  which  the  Soviet  per- 
manent research  base  North  Pole  Two  has  drifted  eastward  toward  Greenland  across 
Canadian  waters. 


THE  IMPACT  OF  LOCATION  251 

enabled  the  Germans  to  forecast  conditions  to  some  extent  over  the  Brit- 
ish Isles. 

Effective  means  and  types  of  transportation  have  been  sought  since 
historical  times  to  defend  the  Arctic  and  to  exploit  its  resources.  It  has 
been  the  aim  of  many  explorers  to  discover  northern  sea  routes  across  the 
top  of  the  Eurasian  land  mass,  as  well  as  the  Northwest  Passage,  which  has 
been  sought  for  since  1610  as  a  short  cut  to  Asia  (Fig.  8-11).  Discovery  of 
such  passages  and  the  opening  of  new  sea  lanes  have  paralleled  the  devel- 
opment of  skyways  and  contributed  to  the  important  change  in  the  spatial 
relationship  of  the  great  Arctic  powers.  The  use  of  a  northwest  passage 
from  the  Atlantic  to  Asia  has  lagged  considerably  behind  that  of  the 
Northern  Sea  Route,  which  the  Soviet  Union  initiated  to  cross  the  Arctic 
Sea  from  Murmansk  through  the  Bering  Strait.  However,  in  1954,  United 
States  and  Canadian  icebreakers  succeeded  in  navigating  the  passage 
leading  from  the  Atlantic  Ocean  to  the  Beaufort  Sea. 

By  using  more  than  a  dozen  icebreakers,  several  dozen  freighters,  and 
its  own  aviation  patrol,  the  Soviet  Union  keeps  its  sea  lane  open  nearly 
three  months  each  year.  In  this  way,  it  lifts  a  burden  from  the  overworked 
Trans-Siberian  railroad,  enables  the  Soviet  Navy  to  move  between  the 
Atlantic  and  the  Pacific,  and  facilitates  the  all-out  exploitation  of  the  ex- 
Finnish  nickel  mines,  the  Vorkuta  coal  mines,  and  the  Kolyma  gold  fields, 
along  with  the  forest  and  other  natural  resources  of  Siberia. 

These  Arctic  sea  routes  solve  one  phase  of  the  problem  of  Arctic  trans- 
portation. A  second  solution,  and  one  which  may  increase  in  importance 
as  an  aid  to  the  exploitation  of  the  natural  resources  within  the  Arctic,  is 
the  use  of  tractor  trains  in  winter,  and  during  the  short  summer  the  use 
of  barges  on  the  inland  waterways  of  the  northward  flowing  rivers.  Both 
methods  are  seasonably  limited,  however,  and  in  spite  of  the  high  cost, 
aircraft  are  used  increasingly  even  for  transport  of  bulky  goods  in  the 
Arctic  regions. 

In  the  face  of  the  growing  strategic  importance  of  the  Arctic  Mediter- 
ranean, the  competing  powers  have  been  forced  to  make  the  extension  of 
the  defensive  and  offensive  capabilities  of  the  Arctic  an  integral  part  of 
their  over-all  defense  system.  The  Soviet  Union  is  ringing  the  Arctic  Sec- 
tor with  air  and  naval  bases,  and  with  radar  and  weather  stations.  Simi- 
larly, the  United  States,  in  co-operation  with  Canada  and  the  nations  of 
NATO— particularly  Denmark,  which  owns  Greenland— has  set  up  air 
bases,  weather  stations,  and  a  radar  net  along  the  coasts  of  Alaska  and 
Labrador,  in  order  to  establish  an  Arctic  line  of  defense.  The  Thule  Air 
Base  in  Northwest  Greenland  is  the  key  to  the  new  strategy. 


II. .1  ( 


New  York 


Fig.  8-11.  Sea  Routes  and  Bases  in  the  Arctic  Mediterranean:  (1)  permanent  ice;  (2)  Green- 
land ice  cap;  (3)  land-fast  ice,  summer;  (4)  land-fast  ice,  winter;  (5)  navigable  sea  routes; 
( 6 )  general  direction  of  ice  island  drift. 


252 


THE  IMPACT  OF  LOCATION  253 

The  Danish-American  Agreement  of  April  27,  1951,  under  which  the 
Thule  defense  area  was  developed,  is  worked  out  as  a  part  of  the  North 
American  defense  of  NATO.  A  concept  of  the  present  polar  strategy  is 
to  build  the  interceptor  and  radar  defenses  as  far  north  as  it  is  possible  to 
support  them,  and  to  build  striking  bases  in  the  same  areas  from  which 
to  mount  attacks  if  the  need  should  come.43  Its  fulfillment  will  continue  to 
depend  on  the  close  co-operation  between  the  United  States  and  its  north- 
ern neighbors,  Canada,  Iceland,  and  Denmark,  and  on  great  expenditures 
of  money  to  develop  this  northern  defense  perimeter. 

This  sketchy  picture  of  the  Arctic  Mediterranean  as  an  ominously  im- 
portant cradle-of-conflict  area  in  which  modern  technology  has  changed 
radically  the  locational  relationship  of  the  Soviet  Union  and  the  North 
American  powers  would  be  incomplete  without  mentioning  that  the  Arc- 
tic ice-cover  provides  also  a  camouflage  for  Soviet  long-range  submarines. 
Their  range  of  operations  could  extend  from  bases  within  the  Arctic  to 
the  trade  routes  of  the  Atlantic  and  the  Pacific,  to  the  very  shores  of  the 
Canadian  Arctic  and,  perhaps,  even  into  Hudson  Bay  where  they  might 
launch  guided  atomic  missiles.  Submarines  enabled  by  atomic  power  to 
cruise  indefinitely  under  ice,  and  equipped  with  machines  for  cutting 
through  when  they  wish  to  surface,  might  become  a  considerable  threat 
to  the  northern  defense  of  the  American  nations.  This  is  only  another 
illustration  of  the  fact  that,  as  a  result  of  the  development  of  new  weapons 
of  total  warfare,  the  Arctic  Mediterranean  has  grown  greatly  in  impor- 
tance as  a  pivotal  area.  Both  the  Communists  and  the  Free  World  no 
longer  look  only  east  and  west,  but  northward  to  the  Pole  and  the  danger 
that  lies  beyond.44 


C.    The  "Western  Hemisphere"  and  the  United  States 
"Perimeter  of  Defense" 

THE  "CONTINENTS"  AND  OTHER  LARGE-SPACE  CONCEPTS 

"We  think  today  in  continents,"  wrote  Oswald  Spengler,  the  German 
philosopher  of  doom,  in  1920;  "but  that  is  too  little  today.  We  must  have 
the  global,  the  imperial  view."  Since  these  words  were  written,  political 

43  "Survival  in  the  Air  Age,"  Report  by  the  President's  Air  Policy  Commission 
(Washington,  D.  C,  1948). 

44  A.  J.  Toynbee  paints  a  dark  picture  of  the  consequences  which  "the  approaching 
conquest  of  the  Arctic,"  may  have  on  the  destinies  of  the  United  States  and  the 
Soviet  Union,  "the  two  still  standing  gladiators  of  the  Christian  Era";  A  Study  of 
History,  Vol.  IX  (New  York,  1954),  pp.  483-485. 


00  Q. 

to  -     \ 

o  jr    JaflS 

o  ,/      S 
°°  ^S 

o      .  ,\> 

o  ^^ 

CD 

CO  tl 

*     1 

o  ^rtr" 

! 
1 
I 

"""""^  .1 
1 
1 
! 

°o 

Do 

7  73?  ^                r    > 

>« 

1      '*^OQ00fffflffl^_      2 

- — Z  .'.■■:: 

a.    m 
to  ; 

v.   ' 

lwMi|i.iy:i!wSES^~~^;  ■■ 

3-         i 

/            ^ — ist* 
1                 /I 

ts^^ii-^s       V 

5y— A           •   *■ 

■I 

i _ 

M 

— J   o 

T  — 

p-  o 

CD 

N  ^o 

< 

S     o 

11/  °s. 

^r  o- 

w$ 

10 

— -,  °o 

o 

cu 

1    \* 

i 

^vwrvy 

u_f  / 

°0   ^}fjv 

o 

o 

o  r 

to  J 

O  "ftv 

e;:     ^-^ 

o  |              J 

o  '  ■■  _/* 

to   fc.  T* 

°0  J                 A 

1     .. 
1 

n 

"^M* 

o 

<NJ 

^^»    /vl    /^  ^^> 

/   •  v\_.     1 
£\_     <             1  - 

.     .;:Zi 

Q- 
tO 

(         ^ 

i 

.    i 

i 

"~~—*— L 

t 
f 

■  --  i 

,.t 

■a 
■  1- ' 

£x  »)      1 

°o 

*       f     1^ 

180°                   160°                  140°                 120°                 100°                80° 

t 

J— — — 
i 

! 

t . 

1 

A 
1 

J— — -"' 

i 
t, 

t 

.  ( 

1. 
-i 

f  ■■•  w 

1 

) 
••.,* ..... 

\<\ 

'  *  i 

°o 

\3 

-a 
v 

s 

o 


o 
H 


0) 

be 

o 
H 


c 
o 


•- 

Cm 

H 

i— i 
oo 

u 


254 


THE  IMPACT  OF  LOCATION  255 

and  geographical  thinking  throughout  the  world  have  experienced  a  sig- 
nificant trend  toward  revising  and  readjusting  basic  concepts  of  world 
geography.  These  revisions  often  cut  across  established  lines  of  areal  and 
continental  demarcation,  in  order  to  keep  pace  with  the  shifting  relation- 
ships of  a  continuously  shrinking  world.  Often  we  find  the  shrinking  proc- 
ess proceeding  at  such  a  rapid  pace  that  the  necessary  adjustments  in 
geographical  thinking  are  sadly  left  behind.  As  a  result  of  such  cultural 
lags  we  can  detect  a  great  amount  of  loose  thinking,  especially  in  connec- 
tion with  large-space  concepts,  and  we  can  trace  seriously  misleading 
political,  economic,  and  cultural  concepts  to  this  difficulty  in  the  redefi- 
nition of  continental  and  other  space  relationships. 

What  is,  for  instance,  the  Western  Hemisphere?  Where  is  the  dividing 
line  between  Europe  and  Asia?  Where  is  the  not-so-Far  East,  the  not-so- 
Far  North;  do  they  assume  different  meanings  if  seen  from  Washington, 
Moscow,  or  London?  Or,  if  we  look  at  the  problem  in  terms  of  the  security 
position  of  the  United  States,  what  concept  should  be  adopted  for  the 
defense  of  the  United  States— should  it  be  continental,  or  based  on  what 
is  called  the  "Western  Hemisphere,"  or  should  it  be  global?  Between  these 
concepts  there  is  a  wide  range  of  possibilities,  from  a  strategy  of  defense 
based  on  the  continental  United  States  to  an  offensive  projection  of  Ameri- 
can strength  on  a  global  scale.45  While  we  are  not  concerned  here  with 
the  strategical  problems  themselves,  we  must  realize  that  in  order  to  un- 
derstand them  it  is  essential  to  see  clearly  the  underlying  factors  of 
geography. 

THE  PARTITION  OF  TORDESILLAS 

The  present  confusion  may  be  correctly  compared  with  that  existing  in 
1493  when  Pope  Alexander  VI  issued  his  famous  Bull  which  disregarded 
the  basic  lesson  in  geography  that  the  earth  is  a  sphere  (Fig.  8-12). 
The  Papal  ruling  was  indeed  one  of  the  most  important  geopolitical 
decisions  determining  the  course  of  world  history.  As  the  final  arbiter 
of  Christian  Europe,  the  Pope  was  called  upon  to  divide  the  world 
outside  of  Europe  between  the  rival  rulers  of  Spain  and  Portugal.  One 
of  his  predecessors  had  already  acknowledged  Portugal's  claims  to  the 
African  coast  when  Columbus  returned  from  his  first  expedition.  In 
the  Partition  of  Tordesillas,  Pope  Alexander  drew  the  line  by  which 
the  two  great  colonial  powers  of  this  time  were  assigned  their  spheres 

45  Major  Problems  of  United  States  Foreign  Policy,  1952-1953,  The  Brookings  In- 
stitute (Washington,  D.  C,  1952),  pp.  149  ff.  (159). 


256  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

of  interest:  The  line  was  drawn  from  pole  to  pole  one  hundred  leagues 
west  of  the  Cape  Verde  Islands.  All  new  discoveries  west  of  this  were 
to  go  to  Spain;  all  the  new  lands  east  of  this  line  were  Portugal's. 
No  provision  was  made  for  what  would  happen  when  the  two  should 
encounter  each  other  on  the  other  side  of  the  globe.  Under  this  agree- 
ment, which  the  two  Powers  formalized  in  1494,  slightly  modifying  the 
Bull  of  1493,  all  of  the  American  continents  (the  existence  of  which 
was  then  entirely  unknown  to  everybody  concerned),  except  for  the 
eastern  part  of  Brazil,  were  Spain's,  while  India  and  the  major  part  of 
Africa  were  within  the  Portuguese  sphere  of  influence.  Greenland  also 
would  have  fallen  into  the  Portuguese  sphere  had  that  country's  explorers 
come  so  far.  The  Portuguese  origin  of  the  name  Labrador  shows  that  they 
were  not  completely  inactive  in  this  direction.  In  1606,  the  first  Antarctic 
sector  claim  was  made  in  the  name  of  King  Philip  of  Spain.46  These  man- 
made  hemispheres  continued  to  function  until,  in  the  seventeenth  and 
eighteenth  centuries,  the  British  and  Dutch  settlers  successfully  put  an 
end  to  this  arbitrary  map-making. 

It  is  useful  to  recall  this  not-so-short-lived  episode  if  we  are  to  embark 
on  the  task  of  trying  to  draw  a  map  of  the  world  which  shows  the  sensitive 
lines— the  "perimeter  of  defense"— of  the  Great  Powers.  In  so  doing,  we 
find  that  we  need  to  clarify  certain  basic  concepts. 

Where  is  this  hemisphere  of  ours,  and  where  are  all  the  others  that 
matter?  Which  are  the  realities,  and  which  are  the  myths  surrounding  the 
"continents"? 

MACKINDER'S  VIEW  OF  THE  EAST  AND  WEST 

In  a  memorable  lecture,  "The  Human  Habitat,"  which  Mackinder  gave 
in  1931,  he  defined  what,  in  the  world  view  of  a  geographer,  are  the  major 
features  of  humanity  and  the  human  habitat,  of  the  East  and  the  West. 
His  attempt  to  set  in  perspective  some  salient  facts  is  still  a  classical  piece 
of  geographical  definition  and  is  quoted  here  at  some  length  because  it 
sharpens  our  thoughts  on  a  subject  of  basic  importance  in  the  study  of 
political  geography: 


47 


The  monsoon  winds  sweep  into  and  out  of  Asia  because  that  vast  land  lies 
wholly  north  of  the  equator  and  is,  therefore,  as  a  whole,  subject  to  an  alterna- 
tion of  seasons.  Over  an  area  of  some  five  million  square  miles  in  the  south  and 

46  Martin,  op.  cit.,  pp.  66,  67. 

47  H.  J.  Mackinder,  "The  Human  Habitat,"  Records  of  die  British  Association  for 
the  Advancement  of  Science  (London,  1931),  15  pp. 


THE  IMPACT  OF  LOCATION  257 

east  of  Asia,  from  India  to  Manchuria,  and  in  the  great  adjacent  islands,  the 
monsoon  drops  annually  a  rainfall  amounting  on  the  average  of  years  to  some 
18  millions  of  tons.  Half  of  mankind,  900  million  people  [1931],  live  in  the 
natural  regions  of  this  area;  about  180  to  the  square  mile.  The  rainfall  is,  there- 
fore, of  the  order  of  some  20  thousand  tons  annually  for  each  inhabitant.  There 
is  considerable  traffic  between  the  regions  of  this  group,  and  there  are  the  fish- 
eries; in  order  to  see  it  whole  let  us  add  three  million  more  square  miles  for  the 
marginal  and  land-locked  areas.  Then  we  shall  have  a  total  of  eight  million 
square  miles,  or  4  per  cent  of  the  globe  surface,  carrying  50  per  cent  of  the 
human  race.  The  annual  increase  of  population  may  amount  to  some  seven  or 
eight  millions,  and  as  compared  with  this  figure  both  emigration  and  immigra- 
tion into  and  from  the  outer  world  are  small.  In  the  main  we  have  here  vast 
stable  peasantries,  "ascript  to  the  globe,"  if  we  may  use  a  medieval  expression; 
tied  to  the  soil;  a  tremendous  fact  of  rain,  sap  and  blood.  That  is  the  East. 

The  West  lies  in  Europe,  south  and  west  of  the  Volga,  and  in  that  eastern 
third  of  North  America  which  includes  the  main  stream  of  the  Mississippi  and 
the  basin  of  the  St.  Lawrence.  Europe  within  the  Volga  boundary  measures 
some  three  million  square  miles,  and  eastern  North  America  some  two  million 
square  miles.  The  two  together  are,  therefore,  equivalent  in  area  of  land  to  the 
group  of  regions  which  constitutes  the  East.  If  we  add  three  million  square  miles 
for  the  fisheries  and  the  oceanic  belt  which  contains  the  "shipping  lanes"  be- 
tween Europe  and  North  America,  we  shall  again  have  a  total  of  4  per  cent  of 
the  globe's  surface,  and  this  is  the  main  geographical  habitat  of  western  civiliza- 
tion. Within  this  area  are  600  million  people,  or  120  to  the  square  mile  of  land. 
Notwithstanding  the  oceanic  break  it  may  be  regarded  as  a  single  area,  for  the 
distance  from  E.N.E.  to  W.S.W.,  from  the  Volga  to  the  Mississippi,  measures 
only  some  seven  thousand  miles,  or  little  more  than  one-quarter  way  around  the 
globe  along  the  Great  Circle.  The  rainfall  on  the  land  is  drawn  from  the  same 
source  both  in  Europe  and  eastern  North  America;  it  comes  mainly  from  the 
south,  from  the  Atlantic,  and  is  of  the  order  of  12  thousand  tons  per  human 
inhabitant  per  annum.  There  is  an  annual  net  increase  of  population  of  some 
four  or  five  millions  and,  as  compared  with  this,  emigration  to  the  outer  world 
is  small,  for  the  movement  of  a  million  emigrants  a  year  from  Europe  to  North 
America  in  the  dozen  years  at  the  commencement  of  this  century  was,  of  course, 
internal  to  the  area. 

Thus  we  have  two  areas,  measuring  together  less  than  10  per  cent  of  the 
world's  surface,  but  containing  more  than  80  per  cent  of  the  world's  population. 
Outside  of  these  areas  is  some  90  per  cent  of  the  world's  surface,  but  containing 
only  20  per  cent  of  the  population.  On  some  forty  million  square  miles  of  land, 
outside  the  East  and  the  West,  you  have  an  average  density  of  population  of 
only  10  to  the  square  mile  as  contrasted  with  120  on  the  five  million  square  miles 
of  the  West,  and  180  on  the  five  million  square  miles  of  the  East.  The  moisture 
upon  the  land  areas,  outside  the  Western  and  Eastern  rain  zones,  varies  from 
Sahara  drought  to  Amazon  and  Congo  deluge,  but  it  is  a  remarkable  fact  that 
South  America  has  upon  its  six  and  a  half  million  square  miles  a  population  of 
only  10  to  the  square  mile,  or  the  average  for  the  world  outside  West  and  East. 
This  vacancy  of  South  America  and  Africa  may  be  regarded  perhaps  as  a  third 
great  feature  of  the  habitat  of  man;  it  must  be  set  alongside  the  extraordinary 
and  persistent  self-containedness  of  the  East  and  West.  The  increase  in  the 
world's  populations  outside  of  the  "East"  and  the  "West,"  even  though  rein- 
forced by  some  immigration,  is  relatively  insignificant.  The  main  growths,  the 


258  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

spread  of  the  sheet  of  human  blood,  have  been  merely  overflows  from  the 
anciently  occupied  regions  into  adjacent  areas— into  North  and  North-Eastern 
Europe,  into  Eastern  North  America,  and  into  Manchuria— and  in  each  case  the 
natural  frontiers  of  drought  and  frost  have  now  been  approached,  except  for 
relatively  narrow  outlets  along  the  wheat  belts  of  North  America  and  Siberia. 
Even  in  North  America  the  center  of  population  has  ceased  to  move  appreciably 
westward. 

In  this  continued  growth  of  population  in  the  East  and  the  West  in  far 
greater  actual  number  than  in  the  rest  of  the  world,  we  have  an  instance  of 
geographical  momentum.  The  momentum,  though  issuing  from  the  past,  is  a 
fact  of  the  present,  an  element  in  the  dynamic  svstem  of  today's  geography. 

Mackinder's  daring  illumination  of  the  East  and  West  as  the  globe's 
outstanding  features  of  human  geography  displays  the  kind  of  geographi- 
cal sense  which  draws  its  strength  from  the  blending  of  a  profound  geo- 
graphical and  historical  knowledge.  To  Mackinder  geography  was,  to  use 
his  own  words,  "an  art  of  expression  parallel  to  and  complementary  to  the 
literary  arts  ...  it  ranges  values  alongside  of  measured  facts.  Hence  out- 
look is  its  characteristic." 

THE  WESTERN  HEMISPHERE 

We  shall  need  geographical  sense— outlook— if  we  undertake  to  define 
the  contours  of  what  is  perhaps  the  most  important  term  of  political 
geography  to  Americans,  the  Western  Hemisphere. 

It  should  be  clear  that  hemisphere  can  be  understood  here  only  in  a 
figurative  meaning  like  the  "East"  or  the  "West."  The  hemisphere  in  a 
strictly  geometrical  sense  is  untouched  by  this  discussion.-  It  will  remain 
an  indispensable  concept  for  the  astronomer,  the  geodesist,  and  the  sur- 
veyor. Here  we  speak  of  the  Western  Hemisphere  as  a  household  term 
and  a  myth.  This  Western  Hemisphere  is  not  a  clearly  defined  concept. 
We  associate  it  loosely  with  the  Monroe  Doctrine.  Because  of  this  associa- 
tion we  are  aware  of  its  important  historical  and  political  implications, 
which  should  make  it  obvious  that  we  cannot  afford  to  define  it  in  nebu- 
lous terms.  However,  if  we  make  the  attempt  to  trace  its  extent  in  terms 
of  unmistakable  geographical  boundaries,  we  find  ourselves  immediately 
confronted  with  insurmountable  barriers.  We  discover  that,  like  the  Holy 
Roman  Empire,  which  in  the  words  of  Voltaire  was  neither  holy  nor 
Roman  nor  an  empire,  this  Western  Hemisphere  is  neither  western  nor  a 
hemisphere.  Political  catchwords  like  "hemispheric  solidarity"  and  "con- 
tinental brotherhood"  lose  some  of  their  glamour  in  the  light  of  geographi- 
cal facts.  They  must  be  interpreted  according  to  what,  under  changing 
political  conditions,  is  meant  by  reference  to  terms  such  as  the  "Western 
Hemisphere"  or  the  "American  Continent." 


THE  IMPACT  OF  LOCATION  259 

CANADA  AND  SOUTH  AMERICA 

North  and  South  America  are  linked  by  an  isthmus.  That  strip  of  land 
gives  but  the  illusion  of  geographical  contact,  "because  of  man's  odd  habit 
of  thinking  that  only  land  is  a  connecting  element."  48  An  illusion  it  is 
because  there  is  little  or  no  traffic  along  that  strip  of  land.  If  Canadians, 
for  instance,  visit  South  America,  they  must  travel  by  water  or  air;  Canada 
is  farther  from  most  of  South  America  than  from  Western  Europe.49  Be- 
cause of  this  fact  of  geography  it  is  logical  to  find  that  Canada  has  con- 
sistently refrained  from  direct  political  association  with  the  Pan-American 
movement  and  "Hemispheric  Security."  The  Canadian  outlook  has  been 
summarized  as  follows:  "even  in  mileage  Canada  is  nearer  to  Europe  than 
to  South  America.  So  remote  a  mass  of  land— unless  the  poorest  geopolitics 
were  to  obscure  the  richest  history— can  never  match  that  to  which  the  sea 
and  air  give  better  access.  From  the  Anglo-Russian  or  Franco-Russian 
alliances,  for  whose  regional  aims  she  has  twice  sacrificed  so  much, 
Canada  abstains;  under  what  compulsion  of  major  policy,  simple  geogra- 
phy or  common  ideas  should  she  discriminate  regionally  in  favor  of  a 
Pan-American  security  pact?  Her  relationship  with  Latin  America  is 
wholly  unlike  her  partnership  in  the  British  Commonwealth  and  her 
entente  with  the  United  States."  50 

Such  thoughts  and  political  conclusions  are  the  logical  expression  of 
geographical  sense  among  British  seafaring  peoples  who  look  at  the  sea 
and  at  sea  routes  as  their  life  arteries  and  highways.  Only  to  continental 
and  land-bound  nations  the  sea  appears  as  a  barrier  to  intercourse. 

THE  NORTH  ATLANTIC  AS  LINK  RETWEEN  EUROPE 
AND  THE  AMERICAS 

In  terms  of  geographical  realities,  the  concept  of  the  Americas  allegedly 
bound  together  by  a  hemispheric  solidarity  is  influenced  by  such  conti- 
nental thinking.  It  neglects  the  growth,  during  the  last  three  centuries, 
of  the  North  Atlantic  Ocean  as  a  core  area  of  western  civilization  and 
the  resulting  fact  that  the  links  across  it  between  northwestern  and  south- 
western Europe  on  the  east  and  north  and  South  America  to  the  west  have 
become  more  important  than  any  of  the  great  transcontinental  routes.  It 

48  V.  Massey,  "Canada  and  the  Inter-American  System,"  Foreign  Affairs  (1948), 
pp.  693-701. 

49  Ibid. 

50  L.  Gelber,  "Canada's  New  Stature,"  Foreign  Affairs  (1946),  p.  287. 


260 


THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 


Air  Force 
£  Transport  SSr 

■frTTTTiaeaaMiaBnnnnnrfe 


a 


1953 

4  Hours 

45  Min. 

Air  Force 

Jet  Bomber 


Fig.  8-13.  The  Shrinking  of  Main  Water  Bodies  in  the  Light  of  Technological 
Progress  ( after  New  York  Times ) . 

is  not  incidental  that,  in  stressing  this  basic  geographical  and  historical 
trend,  a  British  geographer,  C.  B.  Fawcett,  emphasized  that  "there  is  now 
in  many  cases  a  greater  unity  of  culture  and  traditions,  and  a  greater  vol- 
ume of  intercourse,  between  countries  on  opposite  shores  of  the  Midland 
Ocean  than  between  others  situated  on  the  same  continent  and  separated 
by  a  shorter  distance.  Probably  both  Argentina  and  Colombia  have  more 
in  common  with  Spain  than  they  have  with  each  other.  Norway  has  more 
contacts  with  North  America  than  with  Italy.  Portugal  is  more  closely 
linked  with  Brazil  than  with  central  Europe."  51  And  Portugal  and  Spain 
rank  among  Iceland's  main  customers,  as  the  sea  is  not  a  separating  bar- 
rier but  a  natural  link  which  is  important  in  their  respective  economies. 

ECONOMICS  AND  THE  MYTH  OF  THE  CONTINENTS 

Economic  sense  based  on  geographical  realities  has  consistently  taught 
that  the  oceans  are  broad  highways  of  commerce  serving  to  connect 
rather  than  to  divide  or  separate.  The  normal  exchange  of  bulk  commodi- 
ties between  any  two  political  entities  with  equal  access  to  both  sea  and 
land  routes  has  always  been  accomplished  with  the  greatest  ease  and 
lowest  cost  by  sea.  In  terms  of  "cost  distances,"  the  spatial  relationships 
between,  for  instance,  New  York  City  and  either  continental  or  overseas 
points  appear  altogether  different  from  those  which  present  themselves 
if  we  neglect  the  cost  factor  and  compare  distances  only. 

51  C.  B.  Fawcett,  "Life  Lines  of  the  British  Empire,"  in  Weigert-Stefansson-Har- 
rison,  op.  cit.,  pp.  238-249. 


THE  IMPACT  OF  LOCATION  261 

The  cost  of  shipping  one  hundred  pounds  of  wheat  by  rail  from  Kansas 
City  to  New  York  in  1939  was  33/2  cents  to  42M  cents,  while  it  cost  only 
13  cents  to  ship  the  same  wheat  from  New  York  to  Liverpool,  a  distance 
three  times  as  great.  In  the  same  year  it  cost  only  $1.50  to  ship  a  bale  of 
crude  rubber  from  Singapore  to  New  York  as  against  a  cost  of  $1.03  to 
ship  a  similar  bale  from  New  York  to  Akron,  Ohio  by  rail,  even  though 
the  latter  distance  is  only  y25  that  of  the  former.52 

From  these  examples  it  is  evident  that,  in  terms  of  wheat  and  rubber 
distances,  Liverpool  and  Singapore  are  closer  to  New  York  than  are  Kansas 
City  and  Akron.  The  significance  of  these  relationships  in  economic  geog- 
raphy has  been  summarized  by  Eugene  Staley  in  the  following  manner: 
"Land  connections,  which  would  appear  to  establish  easy  contact  between 
peoples  on  the  same  continent,  may  be  barriers  as  well  as  connections, 
while  bodies  of  water,  appearing  superficially  on  the  map  as  barriers,  may 
actually  be  the  most  important  connecting  links.  Because  this  has  been  so 
distinctly  true  in  the  past,  the  existing  patterns  of  culture,  tradition,  politi- 
cal affiliation,  and  economic  interdependence  which  confront  us  in  the 
world  of  today  are  as  often  oceanic  as  they  are  continental."  53  Techno- 
logical progress  in  sea  transportation,  as  indicated  in  Figure  8-13,  has 
rapidly  accelerated  the  shrinking  process  of  the  connecting  links  of  bodies 
of  water. 

The  most  vivid  illustration  of  the  problem  in  its  application  to  inter- 
American  economic  relationships  was  offered  by  Costa  Rica  which,  "when 
it  suffered  a  shortage  of  rice  had  found  it  cheaper  to  import  from  Saigon 
via  Hamburg  and  the  Panama  Canal  than  to  get  it  from  Nicaragua,  a 
stone's  throw  away."  54  Grotesque  situations  such  as  the  one  described 
here  served  to  promote  the  Inter-American  Highway  project  in  which  the 
unrealized  dream  of  a  Pan-American  Railway  had  shifted  to  the  more 
feasible  goal  of  joining  the  existing  roads  and  trails  to  form  a  continuous 
modern  highway. 


55 


52  E.  Staley,  "The  Myth  of  the  Continents,"  in  Weigert  and  Stefansson,  op.  cit., 
p.  93. 

53  Staley,  op.  cit.,  p.  96. 

54  M.  E.  Gilmore,  "Pan-American  Highway,"  Foreign  Commerce  Weekly  (October 
20,  1945),  p.  42. 

55  It  should  be  emphasized  that  large  sections  of  the  highway  which  will  eventually 
extend  from  the  United  States-Mexican  border  to  the  southern  tip  of  South  America 
are  still  in  the  blueprint  stage.  At  the  lowest  estimate  in  1955  at  least  fifteen  years 
will  pass  before  the  entire  route  of  the  Pan-American  Highway  will  be  finished.  Only 
the  Mexican  section  is  virtually  completed.  The  next  steps  are  to  fill  gaps  in  the  1,590 
mile  road  through  Guatemala,  Honduras,  El  Salvador,  Nicaragua,  Costa  Rica,  and 
Panama.  See  also  p.  670  and  Fig.  22-1,  2,  p.  670. 


262  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

A  clear  understanding  of  the  role  of  the  sea  in  economic  terms  and  an 
application  of  the  surrounding  principles  to  the  Western  Hemisphere 
make  it  easier  to  appreciate  the  geographical  reality  that  the  North  and 
South  American  continents  are  really  overseas  in  relation  to  each  other, 
and  that,  in  terms  of  shipping  distances,  their  great  commercial  centers 
are  respectively  closer  to  Northwestern  and  Southwestern  Europe  than 
they  are  to  each  other.  Such  an  understanding,  moreover,  helps  to  explain 
in  geographical  terms  why  the  economic,  political,  and  cultural  roots  of 
the  various  American  states  are  more  closely  bound  to  the  soils  of  Europe 
than  to  each  other.  It  is  in  the  light  of  such  geographical  realities  as  these 
that  we  must  view  the  attempts  to  define  this  Western  Hemisphere  of 
ours. 

THE  MYTHICAL  BOUNDARIES  OF  THE  WESTERN 
HEMISPHERE:  ICELAND 

A  good  illustration  of  the  insurmountable  difficulties  confronting  any 
attempt  to  draw  the  boundaries  of  the  Western  Hemisphere  in  strictly 
geographical  terms  is  afforded  by  Iceland  which,  in  the  spring  of  1956, 
decided  to  press  for  the  liquidation  of  the  NATO  base  at  Keflavik,  half- 
way between  Moscow  and  New  York  and  of  vital  importance  to  the  Free 
World  as  it  controls  the  northern  approaches  to  North  America  (cf.  Fig. 
8-10).  When,  on  July  7,  1941,  American  troops  took  over  the  protection 
of  the  island  of  Iceland,  which  at  that  time,  and  until  June  1944,  was 
still  formally  part  of  Denmark,  President  Roosevelt  declared  in  a  message 
to  Congress:  "the  United  States  cannot  permit  the  occupation  by  Ger- 
many of  strategic  outposts  in  the  Arctic  for  eventual  attack  against  the 
Western  Hemisphere.  Assurance  that  such  outposts  in  our  defense  fron- 
tier remain  in  friendly  hands  is  the  very  foundation  of  our  national 
security." 

We  chose  this  example  because  it  shows  how,  in  the  words  of  President 
Roosevelt  and  in  similar  pronouncements  by  American  statesmen  and 
military  men  in  the  years  that  followed,  the  terms  "This  Hemisphere"  or 
"The  Western  Hemisphere"  were  used  as  if  they  were  clear  regional  con- 
cepts, on  the  basis  of  which  it  could  be  defined  geographically  how  far 
the  United  States  should  go  in  defending  its  security  zone.  Actually,  Ice- 
land is  a  good  case  in  point  because  in  recent  years  it  has  been  often  and 
vainly  argued  among  statesmen  and  geographers  whether  Iceland  is  part 
of  the  Western  or  Eastern  Hemisphere.  Before,  approximately,  1930 
nobody  doubted  that  because  of  the  facts  of  human  geography  Iceland 


THE  IMPACT  OF  LOCATION  263 

belonged  to  Europe.56  From  a  physiographic  point  of  view  it  belongs 
neither  to  Europe  nor  America,  but  is  a  typical  oceanic  island;  only  for 
geometricians  was  it  always  in  the  Western  Hemisphere.  Vilhjalmur 
Stefansson  has  suggested  that  one  "de  facto"  boundary  between  the  East- 
ern and  Western  Hemispheres  should  be  "the  middle  of  the  widest  chan- 
nel" in  the  Atlantic  Ocean  between  the  American  continents  on  the  one 
hand  and  the  European  and  African  continents  on  the  other  57  (Fig.  8-14). 
This  boundary  would  run  to  the  east  of  Iceland,  but  such  a  geographical 
delineation  would  not  conform  to  the  political  boundaries  of  our  day.  The 
Rio  Treaty  of  1947  tried  to  redraw  the  boundaries  of  the  Western  Hemi- 
sphere by  including  in  its  compass  the  entire  American  land  mass,  the 
Antarctic,  the  Aleutians,  Newfoundland  and  Greenland;  but  Iceland  was 
left  out.  The  reason  for  this  omission  was  entirely  political.  At  the  time 
the  treaty  was  drafted,  the  danger  that  these  fictitious  boundaries  would 
overlap  with  those  of  the  Soviet  Union  seemed  even  greater  here  than 
elsewhere. 

As  the  map  shows,  the  easternmost  edge  of  Greenland  extends  beyond 
the  easternmost  edge  of  Iceland,  which  fact  would  tend  to  refute  the 
popular  assumption  that  Greenland  is  within  the  Western  and  Iceland 
within  the  Eastern  Hemisphere  (Fig.  8-15). 

Suppose  geographers  and  statesmen  alike  were  to  agree  on  a  "middle 
of  the  widest  channel"  rule  for  determining  the  Atlantic  boundary  be- 
tween the  hemispheres;  what  then  of  the  Pacific  boundary?  Stefansson's 
suggestion  does  not  offer  a  solution  because  it  is  based  on  confusion  of  the 
geometrical  and  the  metaphorical  meaning  of  the  term  hemisphere.  Thus 
he  asserted  that  any  hemisphere  must  by  definition  include  one-half  of  the 
terrestrial  globe,  while  overlooking  the  fact  that  such  a  mathematical 
hemisphere  is  always  limited  by  "great  circles."  His  projection  of  the  de 
facto  boundary  of  the  Atlantic  to  the  region  of  the  Pacific  is,  geometrically 
speaking,  not  a  projection  but  an  attempt  to  arrive  at  a  symmetrical  con- 
struction without  the  indispensable  axis.  It  would  result  in  the  inclusion 
within  the  Western  Hemisphere  of  parts  of  Siberia,  the  islands  of  Micro- 
nesia and  Melanesia  and  all  of  New  Zealand  (cf.  Fig.  8-14). 

56  Even  during  the  early  phase  of  World  War  II,  Franklin  D.  Roosevelt  is  reported 
to  have  rejected  the  State  Department's  view  that  Iceland  was  "largely"  (?)  a  part 
of  the  Western  Hemisphere.  He  is  supposed  to  have  based  this  rejection  on  the  inter- 
esting theory  that  "the  strain  on  the  public  idea  of  geography  would  be  too  severe." 
(B.  Rauch,  Roosevelt  From  Munich  to  Pearl  Harbor  [New  York,  1950],  pp.  194-196, 
as  quoted  in  A.  P.  Whittaker,  The  Western  Hemisphere  Idea:  Its  Rise  and  Decline 
[Ithaca,  New  York,  1954],  p.  160.) 

57  V.   Stefansson,   "What  Is  the  Western  Hemisphere?"   Foreign  Affairs    (1941). 


Fig.  8-14.  The  Boundary  Between  the  Eastern  and  Western  Hemispheres  According 

to  V.  Stefansson. 

264 


THE  IMPACT  OF  LOCATION 


265 


Fig.  8-15.  Greenland  and  Iceland  between  the  Eastern  and  Western  Hemispheres. 


THE  HEMISPHERE  IN  MATHEMATICAL  AND 
POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

The  confusion  surrounding  the  proper  place  of  Iceland  on  the  political 
map  of  the  hemispheres  illustrates  the  fact  that  extreme  caution  is  re- 
quired in  the  use  of  certain  types  of  maps  for  the  purpose  of  proving 
points  which  are  only  seemingly  geographical  but  are  actually  political. 
In  particular,  one  should  not  confuse  the  metaphorical  use  of  the  term 
"hemisphere"  with  the  well-established  method  of  dividing  the  world 
into  two  symmetrical  halves  for  mathematical  purposes.  The  selective 
term  Western  Hemisphere  for  one  such  hemisphere  defies  definition  in 
terms  of  mathematical  geography.  To  grasp  the  term  Western  Hemisphere 
as  one  of  human  geography,  and  especially  of  political  geography,  one 
must  be  constantly  aware  that  its  human  and  political  connotations  ac- 
count for  the  fact  that  its  content  is  subject  to  continuous  change.  If  one 
realizes  this  fact  one  will  understand  that  it  is  a  dangerous  fallacy  to  con- 
fuse the  Western  Hemisphere  cliches  with  the  static  concepts  of  mathe- 
matical geography.  This  realization  is  an  important  step  toward  a  better 


o 

33 


u 
V 

a 

u 
o 

i- 

3 

6 

c 
« 


H 

CO 
1— I 

■ 

00 


266 


THE  IMPACT  OF  LOCATION  267 

understanding  of  the  politico-geographic  factors  which  govern  the  foreign 
policy  and  the  military  strategy  of  this  country. 


"THE  AMERICAN  QUARTER-SPHERE" 

In  an  effort  to  find  a  compromise  between  the  mathematical  and  meta- 
phorical concepts  of  the  Western  Hemisphere,  S.  W.  Boggs  58  has  offered 
an  interesting  solution.  It  consists  in  boiling  down  the  "Western  Hemi- 
sphere" to  an  "American  Quarter-Sphere"  (Fig.  8-16).  Its  boundaries  are 
arrived  at  by  taking  the  western  half  of  a  hemisphere  centered  in  the 
Atlantic  Ocean  at  28°  north,  31°  west.  The  dividing  center  line  deviates 
slightly  from  true  north  and  south,  passing  through  Denmark  Strait,  be- 
tween Greenland  and  Iceland,  and  just  east  of  the  bulge  of  Brazil.  The 
quarter-sphere  to  the  west  of  the  line  contains  all  of  continental  North 
America,  the  islands  to  the  north,  even  a  piece  of  eastern  Siberia,  and  all 
of  South  America.  Sea  power  enthusiasts  of  the  Mahan  School  would  be 
reluctant  to  adopt  this  quarter-sphere  as  a  useful  American  security  zone, 
because  its  arrangements  omit  Iceland,  most  of  the  Aleutians,  the  Hawai- 
ian chain,  and  Antarctica.  They  would  further  object  to  the  exclusion  of 
most  of  the  Atlantic  and  Pacific  water  masses.  This  may  serve  as  one  more 
argument  in  favor  of  the  thesis  that  no  arbitrary  imposition  of  a  geomet- 
rical form  on  the  tortured  configuration  of  the  continents  will  result  in  a 
usable  political  and  geographical  definition.  "The  atlas  makers  are  the 
real  creators  of  this  artificial  dilemma— they  cannot  free  themselves  from 
the  ancient  habit  of  dividing  the  world  into  two  symmetrical  halves."  59 

IDEOLOGICAL  FACTORS:  ARGENTINA  AND  THE  UNITED  STATES 
IN  THE  WESTERN  HEMISPHERE 

In  addition  to  the  geographical  factors  which  argue  against  the  unity 
of  the  Western  Hemisphere,  the  objective  of  hemispheric  integration  is 
defeated  by  power  factors  which  are  economic,  political,  and,  as  a  combi- 
nation of  both,  ideological.  When,  in  1942,  Nicholas  J.  Spykman  analyzed 
the  World  War  II  realities  of  power  relations  in  the  Western  Hemisphere, 
he  focused  his  attention  on  United  States-Argentine  relations  and  warned 
that  social,  economic,  and  political  forces  combined  with  geographical 
remoteness  to  make  Argentina  a  natural  opponent  of  the  United  States 

58  S.  W.  Boggs,  "This  Hemisphere,"  Department  of  State  Bulletin  (May  6,  1945); 
see  also  his  reappraisal,  in  1954,  in  "Global  Relations  of  the  U.  S.,"  op.  cit.  (June  14, 
1954),  pp.  903-912. 

59  Weigert-Stefansson-Harrison,  op.  cit.,  p.  221. 


268  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

and  a  determined  resistant  to  United  States-sponsored  efforts  at  inter- 
American  co-operation,  whatever  the  surface  appearance  of  harmony 
might  be  at  any  given  moment.60 

His  observations  of  1942  are  still  true  today.  Argentina's  industrial  de- 
velopment is  blocked  by  deficiencies  in  iron  and  especially  coal.  However, 
her  actual  and,  above  all,  potential  strength  as  one  of  the  greatest  food- 
producing  areas  of  the  world  has  developed  a  proud  and  power-conscious 
feudal  society  which  is  determined  to  build  its  own  power  sphere  in 
South  America.  Due  to  her  distance  from  United  States  power  centers, 
Argentina  is  economically  and  ideologically  oriented  toward  Europe 
rather  than  to  North  America.  Her  dreams  of  empire  as  expressed  during 
the  Peron  regime  encompass  in  a  "manifest  destiny"  area  her  neighbor 
Chile  and  the  whole  of  the  La  Plata  drainage  basin,  including  the  tribu- 
tary zones  in  Uruguay,  Southern  Brazil,  Paraguay,  and  Bolivia.  The  Ar- 
gentinians, wrote  Spykman  in  1942,  are  determined  that  their  state  shall 
be  the  most  important  political  unit  on  the  southern  continent  and  fully 
the  equal  of  the  United  States  in  the  Western  Hemisphere.61 

The  growth  of  the  "manifest  destiny"  concept  in  Argentina  which  mili- 
tates against  a  Western  Hemisphere-solidarity  ideology  reveals  itself  even 
more  clearly  if  one  realizes  that  Argentina  is  a  white  man's  nation,  in- 
habited by  settlers  of  Spanish  and  Italian  descent,  with  ethnic  minorities 
which  stem  from  the  United  Kingdom,  Germany,  France,  and  the  United 
States.  It  has  no  Negroes  to  speak  of  and  there  is  little  evidence  of  Indian 
racial  heritage.  The  fact  that  Argentina  is  a  white  man's  land,  a  "Europe 
Overseas,"  assumes  special  significance  if  one  compares  its  ethnic  com- 
position with  that  of  other  nations  of  Latin  America.  The  contrasting 
population  patterns  of  racial  inheritance  among,  for  instance,  Argentina, 
Brazil,  and  Mexico,  together  with  the  related  linguistic  differences,  de- 
feats the  very  idea  of  a  hemispheric  solidarity.  Looking  into  the  future, 
Fred  A.  Carlson  summed  up  the  prospects  of  Latin  America's  racial  struc- 
ture as  follows:  62 

Argentina,  Uruguay,  southern  Brazil,  and  the  great  central  Brazilian  plateau  will 
become  increasingly  a  white  man's  land;  here  the  Indians  will  probably  decrease 
in  number  and  importance.  The  Pacific  countries,  Peru,  Bolivia,  Ecuador,  and 
western  Colombia,  will  become  the  home  of  an  increasingly  homogeneous  amal- 
gamation of  the  existing  Spanish  and  Indian  races,  tending  toward  the  predomi- 
nance of  the  Indian.  Chile,  particularly  its  central  valley,  will  remain  largely 
white.  The  northern  and  northeastern  coasts  of  Colombia,  Venezuela,  the  Gui- 

60  N.  J.  Spykman,  America's  Strategy  in  World  Politics. 

ei  Ibid.,  p.  58. 

62  F.  A.  Carlson,  Geography  of  Latin  America,  3rd  ed.  (copyright,  1943,  1946, 
1952,  by  Prentice-Hall,  Inc.,  New  York),  pp.  15-16.  Reprinted  by  permission  of  the 
publisher. 


THE  IMPACT  OF  LOCATION  269 

anas,  and  far  north  Brazil  will  become  areas  of  increasingly  homogeneous 
combinations  of  the  prevailing  white  and  Indian  races,  with  considerable  pro- 
portions of  Negro  blood,  unless  the  Negroes  come  in  larger  numbers  from  the 
Caribbean  islands.  The  eastern  coast  of  Brazil  north  of  Rio  de  Janeiro  will 
remain  heavily  Negro,  and  the  far  interior  valleys  and  plateaus  will  remain 
predominantly  Indian.  There  never  has  been,  there  is  not  now,  and  probably 
there  never  will  be  a  homogeneous  race  of  people  on  the  South  American 
continent. 

This  racial  pattern,  today  and  in  the  future,  with  all  its  elements  of 
disunity  if  one  looks  at  Latin  America  as  a  whole,  and  with  all  its  elements 
of  unity  if  one  focuses  on  the  "white"  nations  of  what  Peron,  Argentina's 
ex-President,  called  the  "Southern  Union,"  forms  a  formidable  fundamen- 
tal of  Argentina's  separate  power  sphere  and  of  her  ambition  to  be  the 
nucleus  of  a  "Greater  Argentina"— the  big  brother  in  a  union  of  nations 
including  Bolivia,  Paraguay,  Uruguay,  and  eventually  Chile  and  Peru.63 
Whether  or  not  these  plans  will  take  a  firm  political  form,  the  fact  remains 
that  the  elements  of  cultural,  especially  ethnic  and  linguistic,  disunity 
deepen  the  gap  of  geographical  divides  between  the  countries  of  the 
Western  Hemisphere. 


THE  WESTERN  HEMISPHERE  AS  A  POLITICAL  REALITY 

If  the  Western  Hemisphere  is  not  a  geographical  reality,  if  it  is  far  from 
having  achieved  political  unity  and  cultural  uniformity  among  its  nations, 
it  is  still  a  very  much  alive  political  reality.  To  understand  the  meaning 
of  the  latter  we  must  accept  two  essential  concepts :  ( 1 )  that  we  cannot 
define  it  in  purely  geographical  terms;  (2)  that  because  it  is  a  political 
concept  its  meaning  and  extent  cannot  remain  fixed  but  will  be  constantly 
fluctuating.  Politically  the  Western  Hemisphere  has  its  strongest  roots  in 
the  Monroe  Doctrine  which  is  often  loosely  identified  with  the  Western 
Hemisphere.  Yet  this  term  was  not  employed  in  President  Monroe's  mes- 
sage to  the  Congress  in  1823,  and  the  terms  "The  American  continents" 
and  "this  hemisphere"  were  used  synonymously.64  The  history  of  the 
Monroe  Doctrine  in  recent  years  clearly  indicates  the  extent  to  which 
the  Western  Hemisphere,  as  a  political  reality,  is  constantly  changing, 
and  the  extent  to  which  the  two  concepts  are  intimately  associated  with 
what  the  United  States  considers  to  be  its  major  security  area. 

In  theory  the  wording  of  the  Monroe  Doctrine  is  broad  enough  to  cover 

63  Olive  Holme,  "Peron's  'Greater  Argentina,'  and  the  United  States,"  Foreign 
Policy  Reports  (December  1,  1948),  pp.  159-171. 

64  Spykman,  Americas  Strategy  in  World  Politics,  p.  58. 


270  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

both  of  the  American  continents.  In  practice,  from  1823  to  1935,  interpre- 
tations of  the  doctrine  were  applied  virtually  without  exception  to  the 
region  of  the  Caribbean.  It  was  Franklin  D.  Roosevelt  who  inaugurated 
the  idea  of  the  multilateral  extension  of  the  doctrine  when  in  his  speech 
at  Buenos  Aires  late  in  1935  he  declared  that  non-American  states  seeking 
"to  commit  acts  of  aggression  against  us,  will  find  a  Hemisphere  wholly 
prepared  to  consult  together  for  our  mutual  safety  and  our  mutual  good." 
Two  years  later,  in  a  speech  at  Kingston,  Ontario,  Roosevelt  gave  assur- 
ance to  the  people  of  Canada  that  "the  people  of  the  United  States  will  not 
stand  idly  by  if  domination  of  Canadian  soil  is  threatened  by  any  other 
empire."  65  By  these  two  executive  pronouncements  the  Monroe  Doctrine 
was  extended  over  a  far  greater  geographical  area  than  before. 

The  onset  of  World  War  II  brought  further  expansions  of  "this  hemi- 
sphere" of  Monroe's.  In  October  of  1939  the  First  Meeting  of  the  Foreign 
Ministers  of  the  American  Republics  was  held  and  from  this  meeting  there 
came  the  Declaration  of  Panama;  a  pronouncement  clearly  associated  with 
the  Monroe  Doctrine  and  the  security  zone  of  the  United  States.  The 
declaration  proclaimed  a  "safety  belt"  around  the  American  continents 
south  of  Canada.  This  "safety  belt"  ranged  from  approximately  300  to 
1,000  miles  in  width  and  was  designed  to  restrict  naval  warfare  on  the 
part  of  the  European  powers  within  its  limits.66  In  1940,  Newfoundland 
and  Bermuda  were  added  to  the  newly-defined  American  security  area 
as  a  part  of  the  destroyer-bases  agreement  with  the  United  Kingdom.  In 
1941  the  area  was  again  extended  and  further  fortified  by, the  occupation 
of  Greenland.  In  the  same  year  South  America  beyond  the  bulge  of  Brazil 
was  effectively  brought  within  the  security  zone  through  the  negotiation 
of  agreements  with  Uruguay,  Brazil,  and  Argentina  concerning  the  use 
of  their  ports  by  ships  of  the  United  States  Navy.  All  of  these  political 
actions  were  taken  on  the  basis  of  the  Monroe  Doctrine.67 

Towards  the  close  of  World  War  II,  the  multilateralizing  process  begun 
by  President  Roosevelt  in  1936  culminated,  through  the  Act  of  Chapulte- 
pec,  in  the  establishment  of  a  rudimentary  Pan-American  defense  com- 
munity. This  act  of  March,  1945  (which  was  not  initially  signed  by 
Argentina)  in  effect  made  all  of  the  American  states  co-guardians  of  the 

65  T.  A.  Bailey,  A  Diplomatic  History  of  the  American  People,  4th  ed.  (New  York, 
1950),  p.  740.  Roosevelt  later  denied  that  his  statement  was  meant  to  extend  the 
Monroe  Doctrine  to  Canada  on  the  grounds  that  he  did  not  interpret  the  doctrine  as 
excluding  Canada. 

66  Ibid.,  p.  763. 

67  D.  Perkins,  "Bring  the  Monroe  Doctrine  up  to  Date,"  Foreign  Affairs  (1942), 
pp. 253  ff. 


THE  IMPACT  OF  LOCATION  271 

Doctrine,  even  against  an  American  aggressor.08  The  regional  collective 
security  system  first  set  forth  at  Chapultepec  was  formalized  two  years 
later  on  a  permanent  treaty  basis  at  Rio  de  Janeiro.  Article  4  of  the  Rio 
Treaty  ( sometimes  known  as  the  Petropolis  Reciprocal  Assistance  Treaty, 
or  Inter- American  Treaty  of  Reciprocal  Assistance)  vividly  demonstrates 
how  far  the  Monroe  Doctrine  has  been  broadened  since  1936  in  terms  of 
the  extent  to  which  the  United  States,  as  the  major  treaty  power,  is  willing 
to  go  to  defend  "this  hemisphere"  of  Monroe's.  Article  4  defines  in  exact 
geographic  terms  the  area  to  which  the  treaty  applies,  as  follows: 

The  region  to  which  this  Treaty  refers  is  bounded  as  follows:  beginning  at 
the  North  Pole;  thence  due  south  to  a  point  74  degrees  north  latitude,  10  de- 
grees west  longitude;  thence  by  a  rhumb  line  to  a  point  35  degrees  north 
latitude,  50  degrees  west  longitude;  thence  due  south  to  a  point  20  degrees 
north  latitude;  thence  by  a  rhumb  line  to  a  point  5  degrees  north  latitude,  24 
degrees  west  longitude;  thence  due  south  to  the  South  Pole;  thence  due  north 
to  a  point  30  degrees  south  latitude,  90  degrees  west  longitude;  thence  by  a 
rhumb  line  to  a  point  on  the  Equator  at  97  degrees  west  longitude;  thence  by 
a  rhumb  line  to  a  point  15  degrees  north  latitude,  120  degrees  west  longitude; 
thence  by  a  rhumb  line  to  a  point  50  degrees  north  latitude,  170  degrees  east 
longitude;  thence  due  north  to  a  point  in  54  degrees  north  latitude;  thence  by 
a  rhumb  line  to  a  point  65  degrees  30  minutes  north  latitude,  168  degrees  58 
minutes  5  seconds  west  longitude;  thence  due  north  to  the  North  Pole. 

When  one  surveys  the  vast  expanse  of  land  and  sea  covered  by  the 
terms  of  this  article,  and  considers  it  in  terms  of  United  States  security, 
one  finds  that  never  before  "has  the  Monroe  Doctrine  been  given  in  prac- 
tice the  wide  construction  which  its  language  suggests,  and  never  before 
have  such  wide  and  varied  activities  been  conducted  over  so  large  a  geo- 
graphical area  with  the  object  of  endowing  it  with  physical  force."  69 

It  would  be  improvident  to  assume  that  the  Western  Hemisphere,  as  a 
political  concept,  has  reached  the  limit  of  its  expansion.  It  would  be 
equally  improvident  to  assume  that  at  some  future  time  it  may  not  con- 
tract. Its  destinies  are  not  "manifest"  but  are  subject  to  the  political  exi- 
gencies of  different  times  and  varying  power  situations.  It  should,  how- 
ever, be  realized  that  so  long  as  the  Western  Hemisphere  concept  is 
predicated  upon  the  leading  political  and  military  position  of  the  United 
States,  it  will  fluctuate  as  a  political  reality  insofar  and  as  often  as  geo- 
graphical relationships  between  the  United  States  and  the  rest  of  the 
world  continue  to  change.70- 71 

68  Bailey,  op.  cit.,  p.  837. 

69  Perkins,  loc.  cit.,  p.  259. 

70  Early  in  1953,  an  American  historian,  A.  P.  Whitaker,  delivered  eight  lectures 
at  University  College,  London,  which  were  published  in  book-form  in  1954  under  the 
title  "The  Western  Hemisphere:    Its  Rise  and  Decline"    (Ithaca,  N.  Y.,   194  pp.). 


272  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

THE  AMERICAN  "PERIMETER  OF  DEFENSE" 

In  a  sense,  such  expansions  or  contractions  of  the  Western  Hemisphere 
mark  "the  passing  of  the  American  frontier"  of  the  nineteenth  and  early 
twentieth  centuries.  When  ex-President  Herbert  Hoover,  in  1946,  used 
the  phrase  "perimeter  of  defense,"  which  he  asked  to  be  extended  by  hold- 
ing on  to  the  strategic  bases  established  during  World  War  II,  a  new,  and 
by  necessity  vague,  term  in  American  political  geography  was  established. 
It  was  a  fresh  attempt  to  define,  or  rather  to  describe,  the  post-World  War 
II  security  zone  of  the  United  States,  or  as  many  saw  it,  the  pre-World 
Wat  III  zone.  As  before,  the  effort  produced  at  best  a  political  term,  the 


To  the  historian,  the  Western  Hemisphere  looks  exactly  like  the  picture  which 
its;  mythical  entity  presents  to  the  geographer.  Whitaker  holds  that  the  Western 
Hemisphere  idea  in  its  original  form  was  based  on  geographical  concepts,  po- 
litical ideas,  and  above  all  an  anti-European  isolationism,  all  of  which  is  being 
rejected  in  North-American  political  thought  today.  Whitaker  also  points  out  con- 
vincingly that  the  Western  Hemisphere  concept  was,  after  World  War  II,  gradu- 
ally replaced  by  that  of  the  "Northern  Hemisphere"  which  more  and  more  captured 
political  and  strategic  imagination  in  the  United  States.  This  is  well  illustrated  by 
former  Secretary  of  State  Dean  Acheson's  address  of  December  30,  1951,  in  which 
he  reviewed  foreign  policy  developments  in  that  year.  While  referring  half-heartedly 
to  the  Western  Hemisphere  as  "the  foundation  of  our  position  in  the  world,"  he  later 
modified  this  statement  by  describing  the  position  of  the  United  States  as  "lying  in 
both  the  Western  and  Northern  Hemispheres."  In  fact,  most  of  his  address  dealt 
with  areas  of  the  Northern  and  Eastern  Hemispheres  (Whitaker,  op.  cit.,  p.  175;  see 
also  the  review  by  G.  I.  Blanksten,  in  The  American  Political  Science  Review  (June, 
1955),  pp.  536-539. 

71  After  completion  of  this  text,  the  authors  read  what  seems  to  them  a  most  chal- 
lenging study  of  the  problems  discussed  in  this  chapter,  S.  B.  Jones'  Global  Stra- 
tegic Views  (Geog.  Review,  Oct.,  1955)  and  an  unpublished  report  by  the  same 
author  on  "The  Conditions  of  War  Limitation,"  November,  1955.  In  regard  to  the 
strategic  concept  of  the  Western  Hemisphere,  Jones  probes  the  reality  of  the  Western 
Hemisphere  and  its  self-sufficiency  and  defensibility.  As  a  typical  example  of  the  deep- 
rooted  uncritical  Western  Hemisphere  idea  as  discussed  above  he  mentions  a  report 
by  a  Senate  subcommittee  in  1954  (see  loc.  cit.,  pp.  503,  504)  which,  starting  with 
the  premise  that  "we  belong  in  the  Western  Hemisphere,"  demonstrates  the  present 
American  dependence  on  sources  of  strategic  and  critical  materials  outside  the 
Western  Hemisphere  but  maintains  that  through  stockpiling,  exploration,  subsidization, 
and  scientific  research  the  Americas  could  be  made  self-sufficient  for  a  period  of  war. 
It  is  held  that  sea  lanes  to  South  America  could  hug  the  shore  and  be  protected  from 
enemy  aircraft  or  submarines.  "In  the  last  analysis  land  transportation  can  be  im- 
proved." Jones  attacks  the  notion  expressed  by  the  subcommittee  that  Latin  America 
is  "our  own  backyard."  He  holds  that  the  idea  of  a  defensible  Western  Hemisphere 
rests  in  part  on  the  use  of  a  world  map  centered  on  the  North  Pole.  This  projection 
greatly  exaggerates  east-west  distances  in  the  southern  hemisphere,  giving  the  im- 
pression that  Africa  and  South  America  are  far  apart.  The  defense  of  South  America, 
Jones  contends,  "involves  the  control  of  Africa,  which  probably  requires  the  defense 
of  Europe  and  the  Middle  East.  Thus  the  United  States  cannot  contract  out  of  trans- 
Atlantic  commitments  unless  it  is  willing  to  shrink  into  North  American  isolation,  and 
even  that  requires  that  the  Canadians  go  along  with  us.  Whether  North  America  has 
the  resources  for  military  isolation  is  questionable." 


THE  IMPACT  OF  LOCATION  273 

meaning  of  which  was  subject  to  constant  change  from  the  very  start.  To 
define  it  geographically  proved,  because  of  its  quality  of  fluidity,  as  im- 
possible as  was  the  case  in  regard  to  the  boundaries  of  the  mythical  "West- 
ern Hemisphere." 

To  the  student  of  political  geography,  the  realization  of  the  fallacy  of 
the  Western  Hemisphere  concept  serves  also  as  illustration  of  certain 
more  general  principles  in  political  geography.  What  appears  to  the  ob- 
server as  a  constantly  moving  line,  marking  the  contours  of  this,  the  West- 
ern Hemisphere,  or  of  the  Perimeter  of  Defense,  depicts  equally  the 
broader  areas  in  which,  at  a  given  time,  the  United  States  is  exposed  to 
external  pressure. 

UNITED  STATES  OUTER  DEFENSE  MARCHES 

Arnold  J.  Toynbee,  in  his  A  Study  of  History,'2  devotes  a  chapter  to  the 
stimulus  of  the  human  environment  in  cases  in  which  the  impact  makes 
itself  felt  in  the  form  of  continuous  external  pressure.  That  chapter  he 
calls  "The  Stimulus  of  Pressures."  In  it  he  sets  out  to  show  that,  in  terms  of 
political  geography,  the  people,  states,  or  cities  which  are  exposed  to  such 
pressure  fall,  for  the  most  part,  within  the  general  category  of  "marches." 
Marches  are  the  outer  provinces,  or  in  the  case  of  the  offshore  perimeter, 
the  coastal  or  island  defense  bastions  where  the  onslaught  of  the  enemy  is 
expected  and  where  the  military  planners  will  select  the  sites  for  strategic 
bases.  Toynbee's  work  is  a  study  in  contrasts,  and  his  survey  turns  from 
the  parts  played  by  marches  in  the  histories  of  the  societies  or  communi- 
ties to  which  they  belong,  to  the  parts  played  by  other  territories  of  the 
same  societies  or  communities  which  are  situated  geographically  in  their 
"interiors."  The  "law"  derived  from  these  comparisons  is  that  the  external 
pressure  of  the  human  environment  upon  a  march  provides  a  stimulus 
which  gives  the  march  predominance  over  the  interior.  The  greater  the 
pressure  the  greater  the  stimulus. 

It  is  difficult  to  apply  this  concept  to  the  far-flung  outer  bastions  of  the 
United  States.  But  what  is  true  for  a  compact  land  area,  with  its  defense 
stations  distributed  through  the  marches  bordering  its  perimeter  of  de- 
fense, is  also  true  in  regard  to  the  perimeter  of  defense  zones  which,  in  a 
shrinking  world,  constitute  the  modern  marches  of  the  United  States. 
Whereas  the  march  concept  of  old  is  limited  to  such  outer  provinces 
within  the  geographical  limits  of  a  national  community,  the  new  marches, 
in  which  this  country  organizes  its  outer  defense  net  and  military  spheres 

72  Vol.  II  (1934),  pp.  112-208. 


Fig.  8-17.  The  American  Perimeter  of  Defense:  Winter,  1955. 


274 


THE  IMPACT  OF  LOCATION  275 

of  interest,  disregard  national  boundaries  and  extend  to  every  place  where 
a  global  strategy  and  agreement  with  members  of  the  non-Soviet  commu- 
nity pinpoint  favorable  sites  for  strategic  bases.  Thus  the  American  perim- 
eter-of-defense  march,  as  shown  in  Figure  8-17,  stretches  from  the  Carib- 
bean bases  to  Newfoundland,  Greenland,  Iceland,  the  United  Kingdom, 
Denmark,  Germany,  France,  Spain,  Italy,  the  Azores,  Morocco,  Libya, 
Saudi  Arabia,  and  finally  to  the  North  Pacific,  to  Formosa,  Korea  and 
Japan,  until  the  circle  closes  in  the  Aleutians  and  Alaska.  However,  the 
circle,  as  it  appears  in  the  blueprints  of  the  military  planners,  is  far  from 
complete  in  the  actual  picture  of  the  world  map  of  early  1956,  as  a  look 
at  the  gap  in  the  Middle  East  reveals. 

This  perimeter  extends  indeed  far  beyond  the  region  defined  by  Article 
4  of  the  Inter-American  Treaty  of  Reciprocal  Assistance. 

UNITED  STATES  BASES  OVERSEAS 

The  realization  that  the  fictitious  boundaries  of  the  "Western  Hemi- 
sphere" have  crumpled  and  that  the  frontiers  of  our  national  security  zone 
lie  wherever  United  States  interests  are  at  stake  compels  us  to  focus  atten- 
tion on  the  far-flung,  yet  fluctuating  web  of  military  bases  outside  the 
continental  limits  of  the  United  States.  Clearly  the  security  of  the  United 
States  in  two  World  Wars  could  not  have  been  assured  by  military  bases 
already  existing  or  constructed  on  United  States  territory  or  on  territory 
over  which  the  United  States  had  been  granted  trusteeship  rights.  Rather 
it  became  an  ever-growing  characteristic  of  the  American  military  bases 
system  that  the  protection  of  the  American  mainland  was  entrusted  to 
bases  overseas,  the  sites  of  which  were  made  available  to  the  United 
States  by  its  allies  and  friendly  nations.  After  World  War  II,  the  fortifica- 
tion of  the  United  States'  perimeter  of  defense  was  continued  and  intensi- 
fied. The  greater  the  distance  of  United  States  outposts  from  its  mainland, 
the  more  did  they  serve  their  twofold  purpose  of  denying  access  to  the 
American  mainland  to  the  aggressor  nation  and  of  carrying  the  possibility 
of  attack  close  to  the  nerve  centers  of  the  enemy.  A  security  system  which 
is  essentially  anchored  in  strongholds  and  outposts  located  in  foreign  terri- 
tory differs  of  course  basically  from  one  limited  to  strongholds  within  the 
boundaries  of  one  power,  even  if  that  power  rules  as  large  a  territory  as 
does  the  United  States  or  the  Soviet  Union. 

The  rapid  pace  at  which  technological  advances  in  the  means  of  war- 
fare have  progressed  during  the  last  decades  makes  it  necessary  to  re- 
examine and  redraw,  in  shorter  and  shorter  intervals,  the  shifting  bound- 


276  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

aries  of  the  perimeters  of  defense  of  the  large  powers.  This  rapid  pace  is 
in  contrast  to  the  gradual  development  of  the  British  bases  system  by 
which  the  Mediterranean  was  slowly  made  a  British  sea:  Gibraltar  be- 
came British  in  1704,  the  Maltese  Islands  in  1800,  and  Cyprus  in  1878. 

Before  World  War  II,  the  United  States  did  not  possess  a  far-flung  net 
of  bases  in  the  Atlantic  arena.  Its  bases  in  the  Atlantic  were  limited  to  the 
defense  of  the  Panama  Canal  area.  Equally  in  the  Pacific  arena,  the  pre- 
World  War  II  string  of  bases  was  altogether  insufficient  for  the  defense 
of  the  American  mainland.  Partially  developed  bases  were  available  in 
the  Hawaiian  Islands  and  the  Philippines,  and  base  sites  existed  in  Alaska, 
Guam,  Wake,  Samoa,  and  other  minor  islands.  Furthermore,  Japanese 
base  establishments  in  mandated  islands  neutralized  United  States  base 
sites  in  the  Western  Pacific,  and  the  provisions  of  the  Treaty  Limiting 
Naval  Armaments  of  1922  precluded  the  development  of  bases  west  of 
the  180th  meridian  until  after  1936. 73 

After  the  United  States  entered  World  War  II,  and  continuing  until  the 
present,  the  United  States  undertook  to  extend  vastly  and  to  solidify  a  sys- 
tem of  bases  overseas,  and,  in  the  case  of  Canada,  overland,  under  arrange- 
ments made  with  that  country  for  the  establishment  of  a  future  defense 
frontier  in  Northern  Canada.  But  the  emphasis  of  the  United  States'  for- 
tification of  its  perimeter  of  defense  through  military  bases  is  on  bases 
overseas,  while  the  U.S.S.R.,  in  contrast,  found  ample  compensation  for 
the  lack  of  opportunities  overseas  by  establishing  bases  in  lands  directly 
adjacent  to  her,  either  by  military  occupation  or  through  the  control  of 
and  collaboration  with  satellite  governments  in  those  spheres  of  interest. 

Reaching  far  beyond  the  land  spheres  within  its  own  sovereign  territory, 
the  United  States  has  established  an  increasingly  impressive  net  of  stra- 
tegic bases  overseas  which,  in  1945,  was  reported  as  exceeding  400  war 
bases  of  various  dimensions:  195  in  the  Pacific  area;  11  in  the  Indian 
Ocean  and  the  Near  East;  and  229  in  the  Atlantic  area  ( 18  of  which  were 
in  the  North  Atlantic,  67  in  the  Gulf  of  Panama  and  the  Caribbean,  25  in 
the  South  Atlantic,  55  in  North  Africa  and  the  Mediterranean,  and  64  in 
Great  Britain,  France,  and  Germany). 

The  important  part  which  military  bases  of  all  kinds  play  nowadays  in 
the  political  geography  of  any  major  power  makes  it  necessary  to  define 
clearly  the  term  base.  A  "base"  is  not  synonymous  with  "port."  While  many 
of  the  strategic  bases  held  by  the  United  States  are  located  in  insular  areas 

73  Major  Problems  of  United  States  Foreign  Policy,  1948-1949,  The  Brookings  In- 
stitute, 1948,  p.  124  ff.  The  treatment  of  military  bases  in  the  text  is  largely  based  on 
this  source  (pp.  124-129)  and  on  H.  W.  Weigert,  "Strategic  Bases,"  in  Weigert- 
Stefansson-Harrison,  op.  cit.,  pp.  219-251. 


THE  IMPACT  OF  LOCATION  277 

or  form  a  beachhead  in  foreign  territory,  the  term  applies  not  only  to 
island  bases  and  beachheads  but  equally  to  other  foreign  territories  avail- 
able for  military  operations.  Consequently,  a  complete  picture  of  strategic 
bases  includes  overland  bases,  as  those  in  Canada,  and  occupied  terri- 
tories overseas,  such  as  was  the  case  during  and  after  World  War  II,  in 
Germany,  Austria,  Italy,  Japan,  and  Korea,  as  well  as  those  bases  which 
were  established  under  NATO  agreements. 

As  the  history  of  World  War  II  shows,  military  bases  have  been  estab- 
lished in  order  to  serve  a  number  of  purposes,  such  as  the  protection  of 
shipping  lanes,  the  establishment  of  fuel  and  weather  stations,  and  as 
springboards  for  offensive  operations. 

After  Pearl  Harbor,  the  United  States  took  vigorous  steps  to  increase 
and  fortify  its  overseas  bases  organization  to  meet  actual  and  potential 
threats  by  the  aggressor  nations,  both  against  the  American  mainland  and 
the  shipping  lanes  which  constituted  the  life  arteries  connecting  it  with 
its  allies.  Base  sites  were  granted  by  friendly  nations  or  were  seized.  Not 
less  than  134  base  sites  were  leased  in  1939  from  Panama  (most  of  which 
were  evacuated  in  1948).  In  the  Atlantic  arena,  the  United  States  was 
forced  by  the  requirements  of  global  warfare  to  reach  out  far  beyond  the 
string  of  bases  held  in  Puerto  Rico,  the  Virgin  Islands,  in  Guantanamo, 
Cuba,  and  eight  locations  under  British  rule.  Bases  were  acquired  in  Ice- 
land, Greenland,74  the  Azores,  and  on  some  minor  Atlantic  islands.  In  all 
these,  the  United  States  encountered  considerable  reluctance  on  the  part 
of  the  powers  whose  territory  was  affected  (Iceland,  Denmark,  and  Por- 
tugal) to  grant  long-term  base  rights. 

In  the  Pacific,  the  changing  fortunes  of  the  war  against  Japan  deter- 
mined the  course  by  which  the  base  net  of  the  United  States  was  organ- 
ized. When  Japan  surrendered,  the  United  States  was  entrenched  in 
important  base  positions  serving  the  dual  purpose  of  fortifying  the  defense 
perimeter  of  the  United  States  off  the  Asian  coast  and  of  preventing  these 
base  areas  from  coming  under  the  control  of  a  possible  enemy.75  Among 
these  bases  are  the  former  Japanese  mandated  islands.  Now  called  the 
"Territory  of  the  Pacific  Islands,"  they  were  designated  in  November  1948 
a  Strategic  Trusteeship  area  of  the  United  Nations,  with  the  United  States 
as  the  administering  authority.76  This  area  consists  of  650  former  Japanese 
islands  in  96  island  groups  in  the  Marshall,  Mariana,  and  Caroline  island 

74  H.  W.  Weigert,  "Iceland,  Greenland,  and  the  United  States,"  Foreign  Affairs 
(  October,  1944 ) . 

75  Major  Problems,  1948-1949,  p.  127. 

76  H.  W.  Weigert,  "Strategic  Bases,"  in  Weigert-Stefansson-Harrison,  op.  cit.,  pp. 
226  ff. 


278  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

groups.  The  total  population  was  in  1955  about  62,000.  Among  these  is- 
lands, the  outpost  of  Okinawa,  an  island  only  400  miles  from  the  mainland 
of  China  and  less  than  half  the  size  of  Rhode  Island,  assumed  primary 
importance.77  In  the  southern  Pacific,  the  United  States  acquired  base 
sites  from  the  Philippines  Republic  for  a  period  of  99  years  and  secured 
further  bases  in  territories  under  the  sovereignty  or  jurisdiction  of  Great 
Britain,  France,  New  Zealand,  Australia,  and  the  Netherlands. 

In  the  Far  North,  the  most  significant  base  developments  took  place  in 
close  co-ordination  between  Canada  and  the  United  States,  once  it  was 
recognized  that  the  rapid  growth  of  air  power  had  made  the  North  Polar 
regions  and  the  Arctic  Mediterranean  a  focus  of  decisive  military  opera- 
tions (cf.  Fig.  8-11,  p.  248).  While  it  was  not  the  objective  of  this  discus- 
sion to  list  the  various  bases  developed  since  the  war,  and  often  clouded 
in  secrecy,  attention  is  called  to  the  fact  that  for  the  establishment  of  Polar 
bases  not  only  the  immediate  military  targets  of  offensive  and  defensive 
action  against  vital  areas  within  the  United  States  and  Canada  or  the 
Soviet  Union  are  essential.  Equally  necessary  are  considerations  aimed  at 
establishing  stations  for  the  maintenance  of  navigational  aids,  the  collec- 
tion of  meteorological  data,  aircraft  tracking  and  warning,  and  air-sea 
rescue  systems.78  In  terms  of  geography,  the  base  system  in  the  Polar 
regions  is,  from  the  United  States'  point  of  view,  characterized  by  the  fact 
that  a  comparison  of  the  Soviet  Union  base  system  in  the  Polar  areas  and 
that  of  the  United  States  shows  the  latter  at  a  distinct  geographical  disad- 
vantage. The  Soviet  Union  is  in  full  sovereign  control  of'  its  bases  in  the 
North.  Even  there,  where  these  bases  are  on  territory  not  under  the  sover- 
eignty of  the  U.S.S.R.,  the  control  is  complete.  That  applies  to  the  former 
U.S.S.R.  bases  in  Manchuria  (Port  Arthur,  Darien),  as  well  as  to  those  in 
northern  Korea,  which  loom  as  an  ominous  threat  to  the  life  lines  linking 
the  United  States  and  Japan.  The  United  States'  position  is  dependent 
upon  a  co-ordination  of  her  base  system  in  Alaska  with  bases  in  northern 
Canada,  Greenland,  and  elsewhere. 

From  a  structural  point  of  view,  we  have  to  distinguish  between  various 
types  of  bases.  Some  are  permanent  operational  bases  which  are  fortified 
and  garrisoned  in  sufficient  strength  to  hold  against  a  major  attack;  others 
are  limited  operational  bases  which  need  not  be  garrisoned  in  normal 
times,  but  can  be  occupied  in  an  emergency.  No  such  base  can  be  evalu- 
ated, as  an  integral  part  of  the  over-all  security  system  of  a  nation  or  a 

77  Formosa  became  an  operational  base  for  the  United  States  Air  Force  after  the 
evacuation  of  the  Taschen  Islands  by  the  Chinese  Nationalists  in  February,  1955. 

78  Major  Problems,  1948-1949,  p.  128. 


THE  IMPACT  OF  LOCATION  279 

group  of  allied  nations,  without  reference  to  other  related  bases.  Thus 
the  Pacific  bases,  if  regarded  as  an  organic  entity,  can  be  classified  as 
Outposts  (Southern  Korea,  Formosa),  Principal  Advanced  Bases  (Oki- 
nawa), Main  Supporting  Bases  (Marianas),  Secondary  Bases  (Japan, 
Philippines),  and  Backup  Bases  (Aleutians,  Hawaii).  Geographically 
they  can  be  subdivided  into  seven  groups  (including  outposts  which 
are  indirectly,  through  treaties,  part  of  the  United  States  defense  system) : 
(1)  the  Polynesian  group  (Hawaii);  (2)  the  Micronesian  group  (Guam); 
(3)  the  Melanesian  group  (New  Guinea);  (4)  the  Northern  Alaskan 
chain  (Ryukyus);  (5)  the  offshore  islands  along  the  China  coast,  includ- 
ing Japan;  and  (6)  the  Philippine  Islands;  and  (7)  Australia  and  New 
Zealand. 

In  the  restless  years  following  the  end  of  World  War  II,  the  United 
States  had  slowly  and  reluctantly  adopted  a  global  strategy  of  defense, 
thus  repudiating  conflicting  defense  theories  which  were  either  conti- 
nental or  Western  Hemispheric  in  character.  The  resolution  to  prepare 
for  an  "offensive  projection  of  American  strength  by  all  possible  means 
in  all  possible  areas,"  79  is  reflected  in  the  continuously  widening  perim- 
eter of  defense  which  consists  of  a  systematically  growing  net  of  American 
and  Allied  military  bases.  Except  for  a  significant  gap  in  the  strategic 
Middle  East  region,  this  system  had  in  1954  succeeded  in  drawing  an  iron 
line  around  the  land  mass  of  the  U.S.S.R.  As  we  have  shown  above,  this 
line  developed,  in  1955  and  1956,  serious  points  of  stress  along  its  perim- 
eter. In  carrying  out  its  program,  the  United  States  took  the  lead  in 
organizing  groups  of  states  for  their  common  defense  and  in  establishing 
a  procedure  in  the  United  Nations  that  would  permit  collective  security 
action  to  be  taken  upon  recommendation  of  the  General  Assembly.  Conse- 
quently, it  would  be  unrealistic  if  one  would  view  the  perimeter  of  de- 
fense of  the  United  States  solely  in  terms  of  United  States  bases.  Instead 
one  must  consider  it  as  realization  of  the  extensive  international  commit- 
ments of  the  United  States  and  of  the  major  principle  of  its  foreign  policy, 
of  universal  collective  security.  The  result  is  an  intricate  system  of  re- 
gional security  and  of  collective  self-defense  arrangements;  military  bases 
overseas  and  overland  are  the  visible  expressions  of  such  power  projection 
abroad. 

79  Major  Problems  of  United  States  Foreign  Policy,  1952-1953,  p.  159. 


a  s  W   ft  *» 

0)   •-     N    —     H 

Q|  22(2 

g  .O    g    »    3 

«     3    5   *2  C/3 

Nethe 
xico, 
ador, 
ited  S 
rmosa 

r    O    3    S    O 

a  5  a  t>  fa 

ingd 

ates, 

ela, 

Pact 

tates 

M£  3  *>"> 

United 
United 
a,  Vene 
hilippin 
United 

-       3  Bh  *5 

«    U    ti    »    8 

^    o   o  3  ft- 

S^^Ss 

I.qU«8 

nd, 
.  Ri 
ma, 
,  Au 
rmo 

cs   ^  c3  -a  o 

a 

Icel 
man 
Pan 
alan 
a.  F 

nada, 
st  Ger 
Rica, 
ew  Ze 
i  Kore 

ea 

_a 
H 

tates,  Ca 
key,  We 
ia,  Costa 
States,  N 
tes,  Soutl 

_a 

Pi 
ft 

3    60  "tt    — 

=- 

United 
ece,  T 
Nicara 
Unite 
nited  S 

-a" 
a 

"5 

h'c  Pa 
taly, 
alvad 
zus  P 
Pact 

eg 

:hm  g  s 

ea 

r</»  At 
France 
ala,   E 
guay. 
a.  Kor 

— 
*-* 

3 

No 
al, 
tern 
Uru 
apa 

U 

a   3   3  «r    _ 

3 

rity  Syste 
urg,  Port 
iduras,  G 
Argentina 
ed  States 
gdom,  Fr 

Secu 
mbo 
Hor 
lile, 
Unit 

£ 

a   x  u  U  ■*. 

-3 

"> 

Wester 
um,   Lu 
Republi 
aguay, 
ese  Pac 

"8 

CA 

— ' 

g  m  c  a  § 

03    °     „*5? 

4-* 

oo         B  .S 

*C 

8-1 
ark, 
omi 
alivi 
nes. 

eg 

— • 

3 

c  SOpq'a 

P 

280 


THE  IMPACT  OF  LOCATION  281 

INTERNATIONAL  AGREEMENTS  AS  BASIS  OF  THE 
UNITED  STATES  DEFENSE  AND  SECURITY  SYSTEM 

The  following  commitments  represent  the  basis  of  the  American  defense 
and  security  system: 

Under  the  Rio  Treaty  of  1947  which  we  have  discussed  previously,  the 
United  States  agreed  that  an  armed  attack  on  any  one  of  twenty-one 
nations  in  the  "Western  Hemisphere"  would  be  considered  an  attack 
against  all  and  that  each  would  then  assist  in  meeting  the  attack.  It  is  a 
significant  limitation  of  the  obligations,  a  limitation  instrumental  in  defin- 
ing the  contours  of  important  sectors  of  the  American  security  belt,  that 
it  applies  only  within  the  security  zone  defined  in  the  Treaty,  which  in- 
cludes the  North  and  South  American  continents  and  several  hundreds  of 
miles  of  the  surrounding  areas  (Fig.  8-18). 

The  coming  into  being,  in  1949,  of  the  North  Atlantic  Treaty  Organiza- 
tion overshadowed  completely  the  defense  system  which  had  found  ex- 
pression in  the  Rio  de  Janeiro  treaty  of  1947.  Here,  too,  the  United  States 
committed  itself  to  far-reaching  obligations  within  a  defined  security 
zone.  But  in  linking,  with  the  United  States  and  Canada,  nearly  half  the 
area  and  more  than  half  the  population  of  America  to  Western  Europe, 
an  alliance  was  formed  which  "is  incompatible  with  the  historic  Western 
Hemisphere  idea,  an  essential  element  of  which  was  the  separation  of 
America  from  Europe."  80  As  a  comparison  of  the  two  security  zones  under 
the  Rio  and  North  Atlantic  Treaties  shows,  these  zones  are  not  set  apart 
but  overlapping,  with  the  North  Atlantic  Treaty  zone  in  the  role  of  an 
extension,  however  under  different  conditions,  of  the  Rio  Treaty  security 
zone.  The  United  States  is  obligated  to  regard  an  attack  against  any  of 
the  signatories  within  this  zone  as  an  attack  against  all  of  them.  With  the 
United  States,  every  other  signatory  power  is  held  to  assist  the  attacked 
nation  by  taking  "individually  and  in  concert .  .  .  such  action  as  it  deems 
necessary,  including  the  use  of  armed  forces."  81  If  one  follows  the  line 
indicating  the  extent  of  the  North  Atlantic  Pact  security  perimeter,  cover- 
ing North  America  beyond  Mexico,  the  North  Atlantic  Ocean,  Western 
Europe  ( including  West  Germany  which,  while  still  unarmed,  had  joined 
NATO  as  a  partner  in  the  spring  of  1955 ) ,  a  part  of  French  North  Africa, 
Greece,  Turkey,  and  the  Mediterranean,  one  realizes  that  this  line  falls 

80  Ibid. 

81  It  should  be  noted  that,  as  a  counterpart  to  NATO,  a  Soviet  military  organization 
was  established  in  May,  1955,  which  formalized  corresponding  obligations  between 
the  U.S.S.R.  and  its  East  European  satellite  states,  as  well  as  a  unified  military  or- 
ganization under  a  Soviet  Union  Commander  in  Chief,  with  its  seat  in  Moscow. 


282  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

considerably  short  of  describing  the  extent  of  the  United  States  perimeter 
of  defense  which  relies  on  the  military  bases  operated  by  it  and  friendly 
nations  (see  Fig.  8-18).  To  understand  this  discrepancy,  one  has  to  in- 
clude in  the  picture  of  United  States  security  arrangements  additional 
obligations  under  the  North  Atlantic  Treaty  as  well  as  certain  regional 
arrangements. 

If,  in  conjunction  with  the  framework  of  complementary  bilateral  de- 
fense agreements,  we  review  the  geographical  extent  of  the  NATO  or- 
ganization as  we  find  it  established  in  1955,  we  see  that  it  has  succeeded 
in  establishing  the  fundamentals  of  a  united  western  community  of  na- 
tions, without  which,  as  Toynbee  put  it,82  this  community  could  not  hope 
to  survive  "the  siege  of  the  West."  In  terms  of  heartland  and  rimland 
concepts,  NATO  has  adopted  the  rimlands  theory  as  a  valid  counterpart 
to  strategic  formulas  originating  in,  and  conditioned  by  the  control  of  the 
Soviet  heartland.  If  we  concentrate  on  the  North  Atlantic  and  European 
arenas,  as  the  heart  of  the  NATO  organization,  we  will  find  that  they 
secure  the  vital  arteries  which  link  its  members  across  the  high  seas  and 
that  they  bar  Soviet  naval  expansion  and  infiltration,  especially  by  sub- 
marines. On  the  European  mainland,  the  participation  of  the  German 
Federal  Republic  paves  the  way  for  the  defense  of  Europe  which,  without 
such  participation,  would  remain  saddled  with  a  serious  power  vacuum. 
The  West  German  membership  in  NATO  will  eventually  bear  fruit  in  the 
vital  protection  of  the  northern  flank  where  Soviet  expansion  from  the 
Baltic  Sea  into  the  North  Sea  must  be  barred.  In  the  Scandinavian  coun- 
tries, Sweden's  neutrality  and  the  reluctance  of  Norway  and  Denmark  to 
concede  the  stationing  of  foreign  NATO  contingents  on  their  soil  tend  to 
weaken  the  structure.  In  the  Mediterranean  arena  Turkey  and  Greece  are 
the  vital  NATO  rimland  strongholds  which  stem  Soviet  aggression  toward 
the  Middle  East,  as  does,  among  the  Balkan  countries,  Yugoslavia.  Its  role 
is  of  greatest  importance;  in  spite  of  its  defense  agreements  with  Turkey 
and  Greece  under  the  Balkan  treaty  of  August  1954  at  the  time  these  lines 
are  written,  it  can  not  be  finally  evaluated.83  Spain,  not  a  NATO  partner 
but  committed  to  the  United  States  under  a  bilateral  agreement,  occupies 
highly  important  positions  for  naval  and  air  bases,  especially  for  the  de- 
fense of  the  Straits  of  Gibraltar  and  North  Africa. 

Under  the  North  Atlantic  Pact,  any  attack  outside  the  zones  stipulated 
therein  involves  no  other  obligation  than  consultation.  This  consultative 

82  A.  J.  Toynbee,  "The  Siege  of  the  West,"  Foreign  Affairs  (1955),  p.  359  ff. 

83  If  the  Soviet  Union  carries  out  its  pledge  to  withdraw  its  troops  from  Rumania 
and  Hungary  after  the  ratification  of  the  treaty  with  Austria,  such  move  would 
eliminate  some  of  the  major  reasons  for  the  existence  of  the  Balkan  pact. 


THE  IMPACT  OF  LOCATION  283 

commitment,  however,  is  an  integral  and  significant  part  of  the  over-all 
defense  organizations  since  the  interests  and  holdings  of  the  United 
States,  Great  Britain,  and  France  are  on  a  global  scale.84 

Additional  regional  arrangements  concluded  in  1951  fortified  the  se- 
curity position  of  the  United  States  in  the  Pacific  Arena.  Under  the  Tri- 
partite Security  Treaty  with  Australia  and  New  Zealand  and  the  Mutual 
Defense  Treaty  with  the  Republic  of  the  Philippines  ( expanding  the  99- 
year  military  base  arrangement  of  1947),  the  United  States  agreed  that  an 
armed  attack  in  the  Pacific  area  on  any  one  of  the  signatories  would 
oblige  each  partner  to  aid  in  meeting  the  common  danger.  In  the  same 
year,  the  United  States,  under  the  Japanese  Security  Treaty  of  1951, 
established  the  right  to  keep  armed  forces  in  Japan  and  to  use  them  for 
the  maintenance  of  peace  and  security  in  the  Far  East,  while  security 
arrangements  with  the  Republic  of  South  Korea  remained  in  a  state  of 
fluctuation.  In  September,  1954,  nations  from  far  afield  joined  in  Manila 
to  sign  an  agreement  aimed  at  stopping  further  Communist  erosion  in  the 
wide  expanse  of  Southeast  Asia.  The  outcome  was  a  broad  defense  organ- 
ization for  Southeast  Asia,  with  its  eight  signatories  (half  of  them  mem- 
bers of  the  British  Commonwealth),  the  United  States,  Britain,  France, 
Australia,  New  Zealand,  the  Philippines,  Thailand,  and  Pakistan,  pledged 
to  regard  an  armed  attack  against  any  of  them,  or  against  a  designated 
treaty  area,  as  a  danger  to  the  peace  and  safety  of  all  of  them.  The  partners 
are  also  obligated  to  consult  on  common  defense  measures  in  case  such  a 
danger  arises  from  any  other  development  besides  armed  attack  from  the 
outside,  such  as  Communist  subversion,  coup  d'etat,  or  civil  war  on  the 
Korean  or  Indochinese  pattern.  The  geographical  pattern  of  the  SEATO 
members  makes  it  clear  that  Australia  and  New  Zealand,  because  of  their 
proximity  to  an  overpopulated  Asia,  are  the  powers  most  interested  in 
increasing  the  military  strength  of  the  SEATO  organizations. 

This  South  East  Asian  Collective  Defense  Treaty  (still  called  SEATO, 
in  abbreviation  of  its  original  name,  South  East  Asian  Treaty  Organiza- 
tion) is  a  much  weaker  structure  than  is  NATO.  This  is  evident  from  the 
fact  that  among  its  signatories  some  of  the  nations  are  missing  which 
would  be  most  directly  threatened  in  their  very  existence  by  aggressive 
moves  originating  from  Communist  China:  Indonesia,  Burma,  Ceylon, 
India,  and  in  Indochina,  Laos,  Cambodia,  and  South  Vietnam.  Unlike 
NATO,  SEATO  is  consultative,  like  the  Anzus  pact.  Thus  it  falls  consider- 
ably short  of  the  more  rigid  NATO  and  in  particular  lacks  a  SHAPE  as  a 
unified  military  command  and  a  combined  military  force;  the  treaty  or- 
is* Major  Problems,  pp.  88-89. 


^^* 

\                   S3  ■* 

r       \ 

o 

g                       /           |\       >» 

°n 

«                     /          /zV — ^V 

u> 

is- 

1              /          (    w 

> 

■x  (7  \ 

rt   A — \- 

i  A/\r*     y 

o 
o 

E 

ae 
o 
3 

o 

,v> 

=  17 

o 

^.v 

'.h     s  /    . 

JKAr^y     <~" 

•«>_ 

» 

...       j  ,, ,  , 

"""-—NTibi 

o 
o 

o 
o 

CM 

< 
Q 

\      y\ 

*    cts   (  r^ 

o 

■■  < 

J   f  Is 

\  ■      !       * 

\    ™  M 

O 

pq 

\  > '  >  (  y  v_..^_ 

Hgggg 

1 

§            ,  A  H       1        V- 

k  •■'■  ■ 

3 1         £  I          )         V^ 

O' 

w /         \/            \                             \ 

\          l                "    JC                   <               "> 

\        s           y  /••               s 

1      A          SB                 «* 

3      / 

y\K 

<-r           JV  ,l>v^v 

rt  C  \ 

i*^.                                            U>*\^-Lj    ?.,                  ^— v»N 

W  V 

r*          \                            ^        \  _.    C     **>                        * -  * •■■■■♦- 

53    X 

pc^ 

f^          >                -*l   f u 

*  m 

^-^             X     /- — \ir^ 

i~co" 

y                         V.J          Ik  m 

I 

/                       T       cT         ^ 

N 

1                *** 

3  \    J 

i 

^>    >n  V,h   : 

3    w^ 

i\      r^     J   W 

2  /             )                   /               7           ~ 

Z-/                  /                       / 

<)    tr     J                / 

3    (          r- 

(           1                  I                         2 
A        ^/                      /                              w 

tanb 

/                     _^/s.                              L e 

nrj 

A                    I                                                                              /                                            v                 ^5~ 

/  /2   i^ 

If                                       )                                    1                             1               ^ 

^ //     & 

1                   /                                     J                        <*V                                                        ^ 

^T       \)  *r 

U— — VI                  h       \                 7.                            1 

<*.               C 

^^La^Jo  ^ 

F%^ 

'- 
•- 


V 

O 

a. 
o 


CO 


13 
« 

o 

•  — 

- 

T3 
V 

o 
c 

O 


C^ 


y. 

C3 
O 
u 

a 
u 

.s 


s 


T3 

C 

OS 

-a 

II 

3 
H 


c 
tg 

"5 

c 
■■J 

y 

O 


C3 


to 


OS 

i—l 

00 

— 


284 


THE  IMPACT  OF  LOCATION  285 

ganization  is  limited  to  a  Council  with  broad  functions  in  defense  plan- 
ning. 

Large  as  the  treaty  area  is— comprising  Southeast  Asia  and  the  South- 
west Pacific— its  geographical  limitations  emphasize  the  fact  that  this 
structure  rests  on  fundamentals  which  are  temporary  and  far  from  being 
complete.  The  protected  area  includes  not  only  the  territories  of  the  sig- 
natory powers  but  also  the  general  area  of  Southeast  Asia  and  the  South- 
west Pacific.  A  special  protocol  provides  for  the  inclusion  in  the  protected 
treaty  area  of  the  free  part  of  Indochina.  However,  the  treaty  area  is 
bounded  in  the  north  by  parallel  21°30'  and  thus  passes  south  of  Hong- 
kong, Formosa,  and  of  course  Japan.  In  regard  to  these  nations,  direct 
commitments  of  the  United  States  and,  in  the  case  of  Hongkong,  Britain, 
serve  as  substitutes  for  what  ideally  would  be  included  in  an  all-embrac- 
ing Pacific  defense  organization.  With  the  passage  by  Congress  of  the 
Formosa  defense  resolution  in  January,  1955,  a  decisive  step  was  taken 
in  spelling  out  even  more  firmly  the  American  perimeter  of  defense  con- 
cept by  defining  the  no-trespass  line  in  the  Formosa  Strait.  The  resolution 
makes  it  clear  to  a  potential  enemy  that  there  are  specific  areas  which  the 
United  States  would  defend  with  force  rather  than  cede,  even  though  at 
the  time  this  is  written,  the  issue  of  the  defense  of  the  off-shore  islands  of 
Matsu  and  Quemoy  looms  large  and  ominously. 

It  is  in  the  nature  of  a  network  based  on  regional  agreements  with 
friendly  powers  that  its  strength  varies  regionally  and  that  the  line  which 
signifies  the  extent  of  the  perimeter  of  defense  is  constantly  changing.  At 
present,  the  weakest  part  of  the  perimeter,  from  the  United  States'  point 
of  view,  is  along  the  northern  tier  of  nations  in  the  Middle  East,  between 
Turkey  and  Pakistan,  with  the  weak  links  of  Iran  and  Iraq  between  them 
(Fig.  8-19). 

At  the  end  of  1955  it  appeared  that  some  progress  had  been 
achieved  in  the  efforts  to  strengthen  the  northern  tier  by  laying  the 
groundwork  for  a  security  bloc  which  was  to  include  Turkey,  Iraq,  Iran, 
and  Pakistan.  The  groundwork  was  laid  in  February,  1955,  when,  in  the 
Baghdad  Treaty,  Turkey  and  Iraq  agreed  to  establish  a  mutual  defense  or- 
ganization. Britain  joined  the  pact  in  April  and  Pakistan  in  September, 
1955.  In  October,  1955,  Iran  announced,  in  defiance  of  the  Soviet  Union 
which  protested  Iran's  decision  sharply,  that  it  was  ready  to  join  the  de- 
fense alliance. 

However,  in  spite  of  the  progress  made  in  cementing  the  defense  line 
across  the  Middle  East's  northern  tier,  through  a  chain  of  United  States- 
supported  defense  treaty  organizations  and  in  particular  through  the 


286  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

Baghdad  Pact,  this  3,000-mile  front  appeared  late  in  1955  as  an  ominously 
fluctuating  barrier  against  Soviet  expansion  into  the  Arab  world.  This 
Arab  world  is  far  from  being  a  united  bloc  and  the  issue  of  "neutralism" 
(kindled  above  all  by  resentment  against  the  United  States'  policy  to- 
wards Israel),  has  estranged  Egypt  and  her  allies  (Syria,  Saudi  Arabia 
and  Yemen)  which  have  declared  their  opposition  to  the  Baghdad  Pact. 
From  the  standpoint  of  the  United  States,  a  strengthening  of  the  north- 
ern tier  defense  arrangement  has  been  from  the  beginning  an  integral  part 
of  a  policy  aimed  at  perfecting  its  over-all  perimeter  of  defense  position. 
The  efficiency  and  strength  of  this  kind  of  security  system  based  on  col- 
lective security  principles  depends  entirely  on  the  degree  to  which  the 
United  States  will  have  the  full  co-operation  of  its  partners.  As  Secretary 
of  State  Dulles  pointed  out  in  March,  1954,  the  bases  which  serve  in  for- 
eign countries  are  in  general  not  usable  as  a  matter  of  law,  and  as  a  prac- 
tical matter  are  not  usable,  except  with  the  consent  of  the  countries  in 
which  the  bases  are  located.  Therefore,  it  is  implicit  in  the  United  States' 
security  system  that  it  operates  with  the  consent  and  acquiescence  of  the 
other  partners  who  have  helped  to  provide  the  facilities  which  create  a 
sort  of  international  police  system.85  Against  the  Soviet  bloc  of  Commu- 
nist-controlled countries,  representing  a  vast  central  land  mass  with  a 
population  of  800,000,000,  able,  because  of  its  central  position,  to  strike 
at  any  one  of  about  twenty  countries  along  a  perimeter  of  some  20,000 
miles,  the  United  States  and  the  nations  allied  with  her  have  developed 
a  system  of  bases  which  is  an  integral  part  and  a  physical  expression  of 
their  collective  security  system.5 


86 


THE  COLOMBO  POWERS 

This  discussion  of  the  politico-geographical  factors  surrounding  the  col- 
lective security  system  of  the  United  States  in  comparison  with  the 
opposing  security  structure  of  the  Soviet  bloc  is  not  meant  to  suggest  that 
the  political  world  of  today  can  be  neatly  divided  into  two  power  combi- 
nations, permitting  the  mapping,  in  terms  of  political  and  military  bound- 
aries, of  the  Free  World  versus  the  Communist  World.  Such  oversimplifi- 
cation would  be  grossly  misleading.  The  political  world  of  Southeast  Asia, 
above  all,  which  cannot  be  fitted  into  the  not  even  seemingly  neat  balance 
between  the  Free  and  the  Communist  World,  at  the  time  these  lines  are 
written  defies  any  attempt  at  integrating  it,  or  its  major  nations,  with  any 

85  New  York  Times,  March  17,  1953,  p.  5. 

86  John  Foster  Dulles,  Foreign  Affairs  (April,  1953). 


THE  IMPACT  OF  LOCATION 


287 


Fig.  8-20.  The  Colombo  Powers. 


degree  of  permanency  in  this  scheme.  In  order  not  to  be  unduly  impressed 
by  the  structures  of  base  systems  and  regional  security  agreements,  the 
importance  of  which  for  the  defense  system  of  the  United  States  and  her 
allied  nations  we  have  shown,  we  must  include  in  our  estimates  the  great 
potential  power  of  such  state  systems  as  Pakistan,  India,  Ceylon,  Burma, 
and  Indonesia.  In  these  new  states,  comprising  a  total  population  of  about 
550,000,000  (Fig.  8-20),  we  observe  in  the  philosophy  of  the  so-called 
Colombo  Powers  87  a  formative  power-political  grouping  which  cannot  be 
identified  with  either  the  "East"  or  the  "West."  It  is  not,  or  not  yet,  in  the 
nature  of  a  bloc  or  firm  alliance,  but  possesses  nevertheless  all  the  ingre- 
dients of  a  potential  power  combination  which  may  prompt  us  in  the  fore- 

87  This  group  should  not  be  confused  with  the  economic  grouping  of  the  "Colombo 
Plan"  which  originated  in  1950  for  the  purpose  of  mutual  aid.  At  this  time,  the 
Colombo  Plan  embraces  all  Asian  countries,  except  Formosa,  South  Korea,  and 
Afghanistan,  as  well  as  Britain,  Canada,  Australia,  and  New  Zealand. 


■ 

o 
>. 

& 


6 
o 

o 

s 

3 
m 


a 

u 

3 
o> 

C 


<N 


s 

5 

S 

£ 
o 
« 


in 

OS 


4> 

U 

c 

•- 

— 

s 
o 
<J 

W) 

s 

3 

ti 

C 

« 

pa 


■ 

00 

6 


288 


THE  IMPACT  OF  LOCATION  289 

seeable  future  to  re-draw  the  world  map  depicting  the  major  spheres  of 
influence  of  the  Great  Powers.  Named  after  the  city  in  Ceylon  where  the 
Premiers  of  the  five  members  of  this  group  first  met,  the  Colombo  Powers, 
while  divided  among  themselves  by  many  unsolved  problems  (as  India 
and  Pakistan )  and  while  taking  different  positions  in  regard  to  their  secu- 
rity policy  toward  Communist  expansion  ( as  Pakistan  and  Ceylon,  which 
are  considerably  less  neutral  than  were,  in  1955,  India,  Burma,  and  Indo- 
nesia), these  nations  have  in  their  policies  enough  in  common  to  make 
them,  and  other  states  in  Asia  and  Africa  which  they  may  attract  in  the 
future,  the  potential  nucleus  of  a  strong  grouping  with  tangible  binding 
features.  At  present,  intangibles  form  the  common  base,  above  all  the 
history  of  foreign  colonial  rule  in  which  they  share.  Inspired  by  their  re- 
sentment against  colonialism  in  any  form,  these  states  are  intent  on  deter- 
mining the  future  course  of  Asian  political  destinies  without  influence 
from  the  outside.  A  broad  extension  of  the  sphere  of  nations  subscribing 
to  the  general  philosophy  of  the  Colombo  Plan  powers  has  taken  shape 
at  the  conference  of  Asian-African  nations  at  Bandung,  Indonesia.  This 
meeting  brought  together  delegates  from  twenty-nine  nations  comprising 
more  than  half  of  the  world's  population,  and,  in  spite  of  many  deep- 
rooted  disparities  in  the  realms  of  language,  religion,  ethnic  composition, 
and  culture,  as  well  as  differences  in  their  political  alignments  and  eco- 
nomic systems,  united  them  by  the  common  bond  of  being  non-white 
nations  who  at  some  time  in  the  past  had  been  controlled  by  white 
colonial  powers  S8  (Fig.  8-21). 

The  first  major  combining  action  of  the  new  "Anti-Colonial"  bloc  in  the 
making  occurred  in  October  1955  when  the  Bandung  nations,  aided  by 
the  Soviet  groups  and  by  scattered  Latin  American  countries,  pushed  the 
issue  of  colonialism  to  the  front  of  the  United  Nations'  stage.  They  suc- 
ceeded in  having  placed  for  general  debate  on  the  agenda  of  the  General 
Assembly  the  questions  of  French  Algeria  and  of  Netherlands  New 
Guinea  claimed  by  the  Indonesian  Republic. 

We  cannot  foresee  whether  and  how  what  appears  today  as  a  loose 
power  structure  in  the  making  will  in  the  future  affect  the  collective 
security  system  of  the  Free  World  and  its  perimeter  of  defense.  But 
through  the  mist  beclouding  the  future  we  can  perceive  the  taking-shape 
of  new  political  structures  and  groupings  of  great  portent  and  impact. 
Their  still  nebulous  contours  confirm  the  need,  so  persistently  stressed  in 
these  lines,  for  continuous  re-evaluation  of  what  on  the  political  map  of 
today  appears  seemingly  as  a  firm  and  stable  feature  in  the  realm  of  politi- 
es See  pp.  532  ff.,  551. 


290  THE  SPATIAL  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

cal  geography.  Fluctuation  and  change  are  factors  which  enter  invariably 
into  any  discussion  and  appraisal  in  the  field  of  political  geography.  But 
certain  basic  factors  of  physical  geography  do  not  change,  even  though 
their  conditioning  effect  on  human  affairs  is  subject  to  change.  This  gen- 
eral observation,  which  permeates  all  our  discussions  in  this  volume  and 
which  explains  and  justifies  the  study  of  political  geography,  has  been 
expressed  lucidly  by  Abraham  Lincoln  in  his  Message  to  Congress  of 
December  1,  1862: 

A  Nation  may  be  said  to  consist  of  its  territory,  its  people,  and  its  laws.  The 
territory  is  the  only  part  which  is  of  certain  durability.  One  generation  passes 
away,  and  another  generation  cometh,  but  the  earth  abideth  forever.  It  is  of  the 
first  importance  to  duly  consider  and  estimate  this  ever-enduring  part. 


Part 


2 


THE  HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL 

FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL 

GEOGRAPHY 


CHAPTER 


9 


Population  Growth  and  Pressure 


The  legal  foundation  of  the  state  is  its  territory;  but  its  reality  exists 
only  in  its  citizens— in  their  numbers,  their  distribution,  their  biological 
and  demographic  characteristics,  their  economic  development,  and  their 
social  institutions  and  cultural  heritage.  This  chapter  and  the  next  deal 
with  the  population  in  terms  of  its  numbers,  distribution,  movements,  and 
demographic  characteristics.  Later  chapters  will  consider  cultural  and 
economic  factors  in  political  geography. 

We  examine  population  in  a  study  of  political  geography  because 
people,  like  natural  resources  and  other  geographical  factors  germane  to 
political  power,  are  unequally  distributed  over  the  face  of  the  earth.  The 
human  resources  available  to  the  several  nations  vary  greatly  both  in  size 
and  quality. 

Also,  the  human  content  of  the  national  territory  is  forever  changing, 
firstly,  through  the  biological  facts  of  birth  and  death  and,  secondly, 
through  migrations.  These  changes  are  never  exactly  alike  on  the  two 
sides  of  an  international  boundary.  Thus  there  are  everywhere  changes 
in  relative  population  and  manpower  that  tend  to  shift  the  balance  of 
power  among  the  nations  concerned. 

Differential  rates  of  growth  create  pressures  against  political  bound- 
aries. They  create  tensions  in  the  increasing  competition  for  the  scarce 
resources  of  the  earth.  They  provide  the  impetus  for  voluntary  migrations 
and  often  the  real  motive  in  the  forced  expulsion  or  flight  of  refugees. 

The  following  discussion  examines  these  various  aspects  of  population 
as  an  element  of  power  and  as  a  source  of  conflict.  We  shall  first  consider 
population  size  as  an  obvious  element  in  national  power.  Second,  we 

293 


Z 

< 

a. 

< 


to 

Q 

z 


3 


< 

tu 

Z 

roi 

* 

< 

Hi 

Z 

i— 

«/> 

P 

3 
< 

a 

z 

5 


UJ 


0£ 
< 

O 

V) 

Z 

o 


3 
« 

•- 
3 

V 

o 

a 

u 

— 

« 

a 
o 


3 

a, 

o 


« 

C 
« 

— 

es 

P5 


'— 

o 


d 

— 

- 


294 


POPULATION  GROWTH  AND  PRESSURE  295 

shall  deal  with  the  distribution  of  the  population,  which  has  much  to  do 
with  the  coherence  and  effectiveness  of  any  given  state  or  political  con- 
stellation. Third,  we  shall  consider  population  growth  as  a  factor  changing 
the  locus  and  expression  of  power.  Fourth,  since  numbers  alone  are  not 
an  adequate  measure  of  the  impact  of  population  change,  we  will  consider 
the  population  structure  as  a  measure  of  the  relative  effectiveness  of  the 
population  as  the  human  resource  base  of  political  strength.  Fifth,  changes 
in  population  size  and  structure  bring  about  population  pressure  against 
political  boundaries,  from  areas  of  low  economic  opportunity  to  those  of 
greater  economic  opportunity.  Sixth,  this  pressure  is  released  through 
movement,  whether  in  the  voluntary  and  primarily  economically  moti- 
vated migrations  or  in  the  forced  migrations  which  pour  across  boundaries 
when  the  artificial  dams  imposed  by  political  boundaries  are  breached. 

A.    Size 

POPULATION  VERSUS  AREA 

The  ordinary  political  map  of  the  world,  and  especially  the  Mercator 
projection  in  common  use,  very  imperfectly  reflects  the  real  importance  of 
the  political  entities  portrayed.  Even  on  an  equal-area  projection,  which 
eliminates  the  gross  distortion  of  the  Mercator  projection  at  the  poles, 
Canada  looms  larger  than  the  United  States.  Australia  is  larger  than  all  of 
Europe  west  of  the  U.S.S.R.  Argentina  and  India  are  about  of  equal  size. 
The  French  colonies  in  Africa  occupy  a  large  and  central  position.  These 
are  facts,  but  for  purposes  of  political  geography,  they  represent  only  one 
dimension.  Population  is  another  dimension. 

Figures  9-1  and  9-2  compare  these  two  dimensions  in  schematic  dia- 
grams, one  (Fig.  9-1)  showing  the  nations  of  the  world  drawn  in  propor- 
tion to  their  areas,  the  other  (Fig.  9-2),  according  to  their  population  size. 
The  first  is  a  stylized  equal-area  map;  in  the  second  an  effort  is  made  to 
preserve  the  general  geographical  position  of  each  country  in  relation  to 
its  neighbors. 

The  differences  are  striking.  On  the  population  map  European  countries 
assume  a  position  much  more  comparable  to  their  actual  place  in  the 
world  concentration  of  power.  Great  Britain,  instead  of  being  comparable 
to  New  Zealand  or  rather  smaller  than  Madagascar,  assumes  its  place  as 
the  most  important  of  the  British  members  of  the  Commonwealth.  The 
map  shows  Asia  for  what  it  is:  the  principal  home  of  mankind.  Africa  is 
shriveled  to  its  proper  proportion  as  the  home  of  a  relatively  small  per- 
centage of  humanity. 


CM 


CO 


I— 
Z 

g 

CQ 
< 

X 

z 

z 
o 


3 

o 


POPULATION  GROWTH  AND  PRESSURE  297 

Few  countries  are  even  roughly  comparable  as  shown  in  the  two  maps. 
The  most  conspicuous  of  these  is  the  United  States,  where  the  population 
density  approximates  the  world  average.  Most  other  countries  are  either 
much  more  densely  or  much  less  densely  settled  than  the  average. 


NATIONAL  ENTITIES 

"After  rechecking  last  year's  census  the  National  Bureau  of  Statistics  in 
Peiping  declared  today  mainland  China's  population,  largest  in  the  world, 
was  582,603,417,  as  of  June  30,  1953."  x 

Such  was  the  report  of  the  first  modern  census  taken  in  China.  At  that 
time  the  "official"  figure  used  by  the  United  Nations  for  China,  including 
Formosa,  was  463,493,000.  A  leading  Chinese  authority,  Ta  Chen,  esti- 
mated the  population  of  China  at  under  400  million  before  the  Communist 
revolt.  This  range  of  some  200  million  in  the  estimates  illustrates  the  de- 
gree of  ignorance  of  the  true  size  of  the  population  of  this  most  populous 
country  in  the  world. 

There  is  no  doubt,  however,  that  China  has  the  largest  population  in 
the  world.  If  we  may  believe  the  published  results  of  the  1953  census, 
China  alone  contains  almost  one-fourth  of  all  mankind. 

India,  with  377  millions,  is  the  other  demographic  giant  of  the  modern 
world.  Prior  to  the  division  of  the  Indian  subcontinent  between  India  and 
Pakistan,  she  was  a  rival  to  China  in  the  sheer  mass  of  her  people. 

The  remaining  several  hundred  political  entities  include  countries  of 
many  million  inhabitants  and  areas  boasting  only  a  few  hundred  persons. 

After  China  and  India  come  the  two  great  continental  powers,  the 
U.S.S.R.  with  200  million  and  the  United  States  with  165  million.  No 
other  nation  claims  as  many  as  100  million  inhabitants. 

Clustered  together  as  a  third  group  in  population  size  are  three  Asian 
powers  of  middle  rank:  Japan,  with  89  million;  Indonesia  with  81  million; 
and  Pakistan  with  80  million. 

The  four  principal  powers  of  Western  Europe  are  also  of  approximately 
equal  population  size:  United  Kingdom,  51  million;  German  Federal  Re- 
public, 50  million;  Italy,  48  million;  and  France,  43  million. 

Only  one  non-European  country,  Brazil,  approximates  these  in  size. 
With  58  million  people  Brazil  is  by  far  the  most  populous  country  in  Latin 
America.  Mexico,  with  29  million,  is  the  second  Latin  American  country. 
Argentina,  at  the  other  end  of  Latin  America,  has  19  million.  Spain,  with 

1  Special  dispatch  to  the  New  York  Times  from  Hong  Kong,  November  1,  1954. 
Other  population  data  in  this  section  are  from  United  Nations  publications,  especially 
the  Demographic  Yearbook,  1955. 


298  HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 

29  million,  and  Poland,  with  27  million,  are  the  only  other  European 
countries  with  over  20  million  inhabitants.  There  is  a  substantial  gap  be- 
tween France  (43  million),  smallest  of  the  world  powers,  and  the  numer- 
ous smaller  nations  and  dependent  territories. 

Nigeria,  with  30  million,  is  the  largest  political  unit  in  Africa. 

Five  countries  of  Southeast  and  East  Asia  each  have  about  20  million 
inhabitants:  South  Korea,  22  million;  Philippines,  21  million;  Thailand, 
20  million;  Burma,  19  million;  and  the  three  Associated  States  of  Indo- 
China  together  number  perhaps  17  million. 

Three  Moslem  countries  of  the  Middle  East  each  have  over  20  million 
inhabitants:  Turkey,  24;  Iran,  21;  and  Egypt,  23.  Egypt  is  much  the 
largest  of  the  Arab  countries.  Her  population  exceeds  that  of  all  the 
other  members  of  the  Arab  League  combined. 

The  bunching  of  states  according  to  population  size  suggests  that  there 
may  be  some  optimum  or  standard  size  of  state  under  certain  conditions. 

The  population  of  Asian  powers  is  large,  in  keeping  with  the  greater 
population  of  the  continent.  There  are  at  least  four  distinct  size  classes  of 
Asian  states.  The  two  giants,  India  and  China,  stand  alone.  Those  of  the 
second  rank— Japan,  Indonesia,  and  Pakistan— range  only  between  80  and 
89  million.  There  are  seven  third-rank  Asian  and  Middle  Eastern  powers 
whose  populations  fall  within  the  narrow  range  of  19  and  24  million.2 
Aside  from  Afghanistan,  with  12  million,  the  next  group,  including  Cey- 
lon, Taiwan,  North  Korea,  Nepal  and  Saudi-Arabia,  have  7  to  9  million 
inhabitants.  Three  smaller  Arab  states,  Iraq,  Syria,  and  Yemen,  each  have 
4  to  5  million.  The  remaining  Arab  states— Lebanon,  Jordan,  and  Libya— 
and  Israel— each  claim  between  one  and  two  million. 

The  Asian  and  Arab  states  thus  range  themselves  as  follows: 


millions  ( population ) 

number  (states) 

350-600 

2 

About  85   (80-89) 

3 

About  20   (19-24) 

7 

7-9 

5 

4-5 

3 

Between  1  and  2 

4 

The  only  Asian  states  that  do  not  fall  into  these  groupings  are  Afghan- 
istan ( 12  million )  and  the  four  states  in  what  was  formerly  French  Indo- 
China.  There  has  never  been  a  census  in  the  latter. 

2  Egypt,  Iran,  Turkey— 21-24  million;  Burma,  Philippines,  So.  Korea  &  Thailand 
-19-22  million. 


POPULATION  GROWTH  AND  PRESSURE  299 

In  Europe  the  pattern  is  apparent  but  less  obvious: 

200  mi  'ion  U.S.S.R. 

43-51    "  Leading  Western  Powers  (4) 

27-29    "  Spain  and  Poland  (2) 

8-17    "  Eastern  European  States  (6) 

3-11    "  Small  Western  Powers  (10) 

As  noted  earlier  the  chief  Western  European  powers  are  now  roughly 
equal  in  population,  though  the  reunification  of  Germany  would  raise 
that  country  from  49  to  70  million.  Among  the  smaller  powers  those  of 
Eastern  Europe  are  notably  more  populous  than  those  of  the  West,  which 
were  founded  in  earlier  periods  of  slower  and  more  difficult  transport  and 
communication. 

There  is  no  comparable  pattern  among  the  political  entities  of  Africa 
and  of  Latin  America,  perhaps  because  in  both  cases  population  size  is 
determined  as  much  by  existing  and  former  colonial  divisions  as  it  is  by 
the  indigenous  natural  regions. 

Obviously  population  size  alone,  scarcely  more  than  area,  is  not  a  sure 
indication  of  relative  power.  In  some  areas,  such  as  Alaska,  lack  of  popu- 
lation is  obviously  a  strategic  weakness.  On  the  other  hand,  China  and 
India  might  actually  be  more  powerful  if  they  had  fewer  people.  The 
competition  for  scarce  resources  brought  about  by  the  sheer  mass  of 
population  in  these  countries  imposes  a  poverty  that  in  many  respects 
neutralizes  mass  strength.  Conversely,  relatively  small  countries,  like  those 
of  Western  Europe,  have  been  able  to  maintain  a  leading  power  position 
by  the  effective  use  of  their  material  resources  on  the  one  hand  and  by 
the  maximum  development  of  their  smaller  human  resource  through  edu- 
cation, training,  and  organization. 

B.    Distribution 
THE  PATTERN  OF  WORLD  SETTLEMENT 

The  illustration  of  population  size  in  terms  of  continents  and  national 
entities,  as  in  the  preceding  section,  masks  important  aspects  of  popula- 
tion distribution  as  a  factor  in  political  geography.  Distribution,  as  op- 
posed to  simple  size  of  population,  introduces  a  new  dimension.  This 
dimension  is  illustrated  by  Figures  9-1  and  2  which  presents  the  world's 
population  in  relation  to  the  major  geographic  and  topographic  features. 

Perhaps  the  most  striking  fact  about  the  spatial  distribution  of  people 
is  that  the  greater  part  of  the  world  is  very  thinly  settled  or  even  entirely 
uninhabited— usually  for  very  excellent  reasons.  About  40  per  cent  of  the 


300  HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 

world's  land  area  is  no  more  densely  settled  than  Alaska;  that  is,  one 
person  for  each  four  square  miles.  Well  over  half  the  land  surface  of  the 
globe  is  no  more  densely  settled  than  Nevada,  which  has  one  and  one-half 
persons  per  square  mile. 

The  Arctic  tundra  of  North  America  supports  only  a  few  thousand 
Eskimos,  who  are  "concentrated"  along  many  thousand  miles  of  coast- 
land.  Huge  interior  areas  are  literally  uninhabited.  Similarly,  the  even 
larger  Eurasian  tundra  now  supports  only  a  few  thousand  reindeer-herd- 
ing nomads,  except  where  mineral  resources  have  attracted  a  small  non- 
indigenous  population.  The  sub-Arctic  forest,  the  taiga,  which  stretches 
across  North  America  and  Eurasia  in  a  belt  five  hundred  to  a  thousand 
miles  in  width,  has  scarcely  been  penetrated  anywhere  by  intensive  set- 
tlement. The  vast  deserts  and  steppes  of  the  American  West,  of  Central 
Asia,  of  Asia  Minor,  of  the  Sahara,  and  of  Australia  have  repelled  close 
settlement  over  most  of  these  enormous  interior  regions.  Yet  together 
these  encompass  close  to  half  the  land  surface  of  the  globe.  This  half  of 
the  world  receives  less  than  twenty  inches  of  rainfall  annually,  which  is 
usually  insufficient  to  support  profitable  dry  farming. 

For  quite  the  opposite  reasons  the  Amazon  and  Congo  Basins  have 
resisted  intensive  human  settlement.  Here,  there  is  too  much  rainfall.  The 
tropical  soils  are  leached  of  essential  minerals  necessary  for  high  agricul- 
tural output.  The  cost  of  clearing  jungle  land  is  often  excessive  in  terms 
of  any  realizable  economic  return. 

In  short,  most  of  the  world  is  too  cold  or  too  hot,  too  dry  or  too  wet, 
too  high  or  too  low  to  provide  the  conditions  suitable  for  intensive  human 
settlement. 

Most  of  us  live  in  great  clusters  of  population.  Three-fourths  of  the 
world's  people  live  in  four  of  these  clusters,  those  of  East  Asia,  the  Indian 
subcontinent,  Europe,  and  Eastern  North  America.  These  four  are 
roughly  comparable  in  area  and  population,  except  that  the  population 
concentration  in  Eastern  North  America  falls  far  below  the  other  great 
centers  of  mankind. 

East  Asia  (650-800  million  people).  This  greatest  concentration  of  hu- 
manity includes  China,  Korea,  Japan,  and  the  portion  of  Indo-China 
neighboring  on  China  (Viet  Minh).  The  high  population  density  in 
North  China  and  neighboring  areas  around  the  China  Sea  reflect  the 
North  Chinese  origin  of  the  civilization  created  by  this  largest  mass  of 
mankind. 

The  agricultural  base  of  East  Asian  life  is  reflected  in  the  extensive 
area  of  dense  settlement.  There  are  few  major  cities  except  in  industrial- 


POPULATION  GROWTH  AND  PRESSURE  301 

ized  Japan.  The  Chinese  and  Korean  population  distribution  closely  fol- 
lows the  topography,  soil,  and  rainfall  conditions  suitable  for  intensive 
agriculture.  However,  the  lesser  density  in  South  China  also  in  part  re- 
flects its  peripheral  and  marginal  relation  to  the  main  centers  in  the 
North.  This  lower  density  of  population  has  in  recent  times  led  to  sub- 
stantially better  living  conditions  in  South  China  than  in  the  North.  Con- 
sequently there  has  been  a  considerable  movement  of  the  more  industri- 
ous and  frugal  North  Chinese  to  the  South. 

It  is  obvious  that  the  weight  of  human  resources  in  the  area  lies  in 
China  and  not  in  Japan.  Formerly  the  latter  was  able  to  profit  by  the  lack 
of  integration  of  the  great  Chinese  mass.  Until  very  recent  times  the 
sprawling  Chinese  dragon  has  lacked  an  effective  head.  In  addition  to 
many  local  and  separatist  tendencies,  there  has  been  a  struggle  between 
two  centers  of  power  in  the  core  area  of  settlement  in  the  North  China 
plain.3  This  has  been  symbolized  by  the  migration  of  the  capital  between 
Peking  (literally  "the  northern  capital")  and  Nanking  ("the  southern 
capital")  (cf.  Fig.  6-5,  p.  154).  Peking  represents  the  traditional  political 
dominance  of  China  from  the  north,  and  by  continental  people  from 
Central  Asia.  This  domination  was  reflected  in  the  Manchu  dynasty,  the 
last  to  rule  China  as  an  Empire.  It  is  also  reflected  in  the  role  of  the  Com- 
munists, who  found  their  strongest  roots  in  the  land  of  the  northern  prov- 
inces. It  is  natural  that  the  Communists  should  have  revived  the  leader- 
ship of  Peking  as  opposed  to  Nanking  and  the  great  port  city  of  Shanghai, 
which  were  centers  of  commerce  and  foreign  economic  penetration.  It  is 
scarcely  necessary  to  emphasize  that  implicit  in  the  success  of  the  Com- 
munist movement  in  China  there  was  a  massive  repudiation  of  influences 
which  have  come  to  China  via  the  sea,  and  which  were  so  strong  in  the 
modern  development  of  Japan.  The  Communists  have  renounced  these 
in  favor  of  the  continental  China  governed  from  Peking. 

The  Indian  Subcontinent  (450  million  people).  The  population  of  the 
Indian  subcontinent  is  effectively  set  off  from  other  great  centers  by  im- 
pressive barriers  of  mountain  and  desert.  Nevertheless,  the  Indian  popu- 
lation cluster  is  somewhat  less  coherent  in  pattern  than  that  of  East  Asia, 
and  this  is  perhaps  one  reason  why  this  cluster  has  never  in  the  past 
served  as  the  demographic  base  for  a  single  world  power.  Even  the  great 
Mogul  empires  of  the  fifteenth  to  the  seventeenth  centuries  were  never 
successful  in  bringing  the  entire  subcontinent  under  one  rule. 

An  examination  of  Indian  population  distribution  4  will  suggest  why  this 

3  See  pp.  153  ff. 

4  Cf.  O.  H.  K.  Spate,  Geography  of  India  and  Pakistan  (London,  1954),  pp.  491-493. 


302  HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 

has  been  the  case.  The  core  area  of  India  is  the  rich  plain  of  the  upper 
Indus  and  Ganges  Rivers.  Somewhat  separated  from  this  main  concentra- 
tion by  the  arid  Deccan  are  other  but  smaller  concentrations  of  population 
in  South  India.  This  distribution  suggests  a  clear  base  for  separatist  tend- 
encies in  South  India.  These  have  been  accentuated  by  the  survival  of 
Dravidian  languages  and  influences  in  the  South  as  opposed  to  the  pre- 
vailing Indo-Aryan  languages  which  were  spread  across  India  by  suc- 
cessive invasions  from  the  Northwest. 

The  core  area  of  settlement  stretches  from  the  Punjab  in  the  Northwest 
to  Bengal  in  the  East.  As  in  China  there  is  a  conflicting  pull  between  the 
continental  foci  of  power,  represented  by  New  Delhi,  and  the  economic 
and  maritime  focus  of  power  at  the  mouth  of  the  Ganges,  represented  by 
Calcutta.  It  is  significant  that  Calcutta  was  the  first  British  capital  of 
India.  It  is  still  much  the  largest  city  in  the  country.  But  New  Delhi  rep- 
resents the  traditional  administration  of  India  from  centers  in  the  ecumene 
that  are  nearest  the  original  overland  sources  of  conquest  and  political 
power. 

The  highly  artificial  division  of  India  and  Pakistan  highlights  this  prob- 
lem. Pakistan  includes  the  two  ends  of  the  main  Indian  population  cluster, 
one  in  the  Punjab  and  the  other  in  Bengal.  The  western  portion  includes 
the  less  populous  northwestern  areas  which  however  are  the  traditional 
centers  of  aggressive  Moslem  leadership  in  India.  But  the  main  population 
weight  of  Pakistan  is  at  the  other  end,  in  Bengal.  This  is  inevitably  an 
unstable  political  relationship.  This  instability  is  currently  pointed  up  by 
the  increasing  restlessness  of  East  Bengal  within  the  Pakistan  union. 

Europe  (600  million  people).  Despite  its  fracture  into  many  political 
entities,  Europe  is  essentially  a  single  cluster  of  population.  National 
boundaries  conceal  an  organized  pattern  of  settlement  reflecting  economic 
forces  older  and  more  fundamental  than  present  political  entities.  The 
center  of  European  population  lies  in  a  core  area  including  England,  the 
Low  Countries,  Northern  France,  Western  Germany,  Switzerland,  and 
Northern  Italy.  To  the  East  the  European  settlement  area  reaches  out 
across  the  Russian  plain  into  Siberia,  through  the  Balkans  to  West  Ana- 
tolia, and  across  the  Mediterranean  to  French  North  Africa,  which  is  in 
some  respects  a  part  of  Mediterranean  Europe. 

The  pattern  of  European  population  distribution  reflects  history  as  well 
as  contemporary  fact.  Originally  it  was  Mediterranean-oriented  with  the 
densest  population  bordering  on  that  Sea.  Superimposed  on  this  in  the 
modern  era  has  been,  firstly,  an  Atlantic  and  especially  North  Sea  orien- 


POPULATION  GROWTH  AND  PRESSURE  303 

tation,  which  has  grown  out  of  the  influence  of  overseas  trade.  In  this 
regard  we  may  note  the  heavy  concentration  of  cities  in  the  countries  bor- 
dering on  the  North  Sea.  Secondly,  there  has  been  an  eastward  march  of 
European  settlement.  Since  1500  probably  as  much  new  land  has  been 
firmly  settled  and  occupied  by  Europeans  in  Eastern  Europe  and  Asia  as 
has  been  so  occupied  in  North  America.  There  is  a  great  wedge  of  Euro- 
pean settlement  pushing  across  Eurasia  along  a  narrowing  base  of  good 
agricultural  land.  This  wedge  is  broad  at  its  European  base,  but  as  it 
pushes  into  Asia,  it  is  progressively  cramped  by  cold  on  the  north  and 
desert  to  the  south. 

While  the  European  settlement  area  has  as  large  a  population  and  con- 
tains as  much  agricultural  production  area  as  the  two  great  Asian  clusters, 
it  does  not  display  as  heavy  rural  settlement.  The  explanation  is  of  course 
that  industrialization  in  Europe  has  resulted  in  the  rise  of  great  cities  and 
conurbations  that  together  include  a  large  part  of  the  total  population  of 
the  continent. 

In  Europe,  even  more  acutely  than  in  Asia,  there  is  a  conflict  between 
the  maritime  commercial  interests  centered  in  the  North  Sea  and  the  con- 
tinental foci  of  power  in  Russia.  In  its  broadest  terms  the  East-West  con- 
flict may  be  thought  of  as  a  struggle  between  the  conflicting  poles  of  the 
older  maritime  civilization  of  the  West  and  the  continental  interests  of 
the  East  created  by  European  settlement  in  the  last  three  or  four  hundred 
years. 

Eastern  North  America  ( 150  million  people ) .  Eastern  North  America, 
as  far  west  as  the  Rocky  Mountains,  is  basically  a  mirror  image  of  North- 
west Europe.  There  is  a  concentration  of  population  in  the  habitable  area 
closest  in  character  to  that  of  the  North  Sea  progenitor-countries.  There  is 
an  axis  of  industrial  urban  settlement  in  the  Northeast.  This  industrial 
area  is  anchored  on  the  one  side  by  the  great  metropolitan  region  now 
extending  almost  continuously  along  the  coast  from  Boston  to  Washing- 
ton. From  this  coastal  base  it  extends  westward  to  include  the  North 
Central  States  and  the  Great  Lakes  region.  This  is  the  American  counter- 
part of  the  great  industrial  and  commercial  region  of  Northwest  Europe. 
This  industrial  belt  reaches  from  England  across  France  and  the  Low 
Countries  to  include  much  of  Germany,  Bohemia,  and  Northern  Italy. 

From  the  industrial  northeast  population  density  declines  toward  the 
southeast  (as  it  does  toward  the  southwest  in  Europe).  The  Mississippi 
Valley  is  the  American  counterpart  of  the  European  plain.  The  Middle 
West  was  never  settled  agriculturally  as  densely  as  the  European  plain 


304  HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 

because  its  settlement  occurred  in  competition  with  industrialization  and 
the  growing  cityward  movements  of  the  past  hundred  years.  The  great 
European  immigration  from  1880  to  1914  was  a  migration  from  European 
villages  to  American  cities  rather  than  to  the  land  in  this  country.  The 
United  States  and  Canada  are  much  more  urban  than  Europe,  where 
agricultural  settlement  much  antedated  modern  industrialization. 

As  compared  with  the  other  population  clusters,  that  of  Eastern  North 
America  has  two  tremendous  advantages :  ( 1 )  the  region  is  and  has  been 
politically  unified  for  150  years,  aside  from  the  friendly  boundary  that 
separates  out  the  comparatively  small  Canadian  population;  (2)  the  re- 
gion has  resources  at  least  equaling  those  available  to  the  other  great 
population  clusters  and  is  able  to  utilize  these  resources  for  the  advantage 
of  a  very  much  smaller  population. 

A  third  and  less  specific  advantage  lies  in  the  fact  that  the  core  area 
centering  in  New  York  City  has  maintained  essentially  undisputed  domi- 
nation of  the  economic  life  of  the  region.  Numerous  political  movements 
have  reflected  the  emergence  of  continental  interests  in  the  Middle  West 
comparable  to  those  which  have  brought  about  the  breaking  off  of  Russia 
and  Eastern  Europe  from  the  main  cultural  stream  of  Western  Europe. 
These  movements  have  been  variously  given  the  labels  of  agrarian,  popu- 
list, isolationist,  et  cetera,  but  have  never  reached  the  strength  nor  the 
intensity  to  bring  about  a  schism  since  the  Civil  War. 

The  West  Coast  of  North  America  is  of  course  an  integral  part  of  Anglo- 
America,  but  in  terms  of  population  geography  the  pattern  of  West  Coast 
settlement  is  not  closely  linked  to  that  of  Eastern  North  America.  As  might 
be  expected,  it  reflects  an  orientation  toward  the  Pacific.  Being  more  re- 
cently settled  than  Eastern  North  America,  it  is  even  more  urban  and  has 
even  less  agricultural  settlement  and  hinterland. 

Australia,  New  Zealand,  and  Argentina  are  likewise  more  urbanized 
than  Europe  and  for  the  same  reasons. 

As  has  been  pointed  out  above,  the  four  great  clusters  include  three- 
fourths  of  the  world's  people.  The  remaining  one-fourth  are  dispersed  in 
the  smaller  clusters  of  Latin  America,  Africa,  Southeast  Asia,  arid  Asia, 
and  Oceania. 

Latin  America.  Latin  America  has  no  real  population  center  and  hence 
no  ecumene  to  serve  as  a  base  for  continental  power  on  the  scale  of  that 
realized  by  China,  India,  the  U.S.S.R.,  and  the  U.S.  The  present  distribu- 
tion of  population  in  Latin  America  has  two  chief  features :  ( a )  European 
settlement  and  influence  superimposed  on  the  ancient  centers  of  Amerin- 
dian civilization.  The  ancient  Aztec  and  Incan  civilizations  are  still  re- 


POPULATION  GROWTH  AND  PRESSURE  305 

fleeted  in  the  concentrations  of  people  in  the  highlands  of  Mexico  and 
Central  America  and  in  the  Andean  intermountain  valleys  from  Venezuela 
to  Bolivia  and  Chile;  (b)  scattered  African  and  European  settlement  on 
the  Caribbean  Islands  and  on  the  coasts  of  South  America. 

There  has  been  relatively  little  penetration  of  the  great  lowland  interior 
of  South  America.  In  effect  there  is  a  thin  rim  of  settlement  around  a  hol- 
low interior.  In  some  local  regions  of  Latin  America  there  are  quite  dense 
populations  and  even  signs  of  overpopulation,  as  in  many  Andean  valleys, 
on  the  islands  of  Santo  Domingo,  Puerto  Rico,  and  certain  of  the  other 
West  Indies,  and  in  El  Salvador.  But  there  is  no  core  of  population  large 
enough  to  serve  at  this  time  as  the  assured  base  of  a  continental  and  world 
power.  The  political  fractioning  of  Latin  America  reflects  this  lack. 

Africa.  Africa  is  no  more  densely  settled  than  South  America  but  it  is 
not  demographically  a  "hollow"  continent  in  the  same  sense  as  South 
America.  North  Africa  and  Egypt  are  not  truly  African  in  demographic, 
economic,  or  political  orientation.  This  area  is  a  part  of  Africa  by  courtesy 
of  geography  rather  than  of  culture  or  economics.  French  North  Africa 
is  of  course  Mediterranean  in  orientation  but  Arab  in  culture.  Egypt  and 
the  neighboring  states  of  the  Levant  form  a  minor  population  cluster  that 
is  also  Mediterranean-oriented  and  of  course  older  than  even  that  of 
Southern  Europe. 

But  Africa  really  begins  beyond  the  Sahara.  In  Black  Africa  there  are 
significant  clusters  of  interior  settlement  and  the  overlay  of  European 
settlement  is  important  only  in  the  Union  of  South  Africa.  Politically 
Africa  is  artificially  divided  with  regard  to  little  more  than  the  reconcilia- 
tion of  nineteenth  century  rivalries  of  European  colonial  powers.  Conse- 
quently, there  is  little  relationship  between  the  distribution  of  population 
and  of  political  organization. 

With  the  probability  that  most  of  Black  Africa  will  sooner  or  later 
emerge  from  political  dependency,  attention  needs  to  be  given  to  the  pos- 
sible locus  of  emerging  African  power.  At  the  present  time  there  would 
seem  to  be  two  potential  competitors  for  leadership  in  the  development 
of  native  African  political  power.  In  West  Africa  and  particularly  in  Ni- 
geria there  is  a  considerable  population  base  for  political  and  economic 
power.  The  total  population  size  may  be  deceptive,  however,  since  there 
is  a  conflicting  pull  between  the  coastal  areas,  where  trade  and  the  begin- 
nings of  modern  economy  are  concentrated,  and  the  interior  areas  which 
are  both  more  Moslem  and  more  militant.  A  possible  competing  ecumene 
lies  in  the  highlands  of  East  Africa  along  the  great  Rift  Valley  of  East 
Africa  and  on  the  shores  of  Lakes  Victoria  and  Tanganyika.  This  area  is 


306  HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 

now  divided  politically  between  Uganda,  Tanganyika,  Ruanda-Urundi, 
and  the  Belgian  Congo.  The  Union  of  South  Africa  is  thinly  populated 
but  has  the  only  large  cities  and  industrial  centers  south  of  the  Sahara. 

Southeast  Asia.  In  Southeast  Asia  there  are  several  minor  centers  of 
population  focused  on  major  river  valleys  such  as  the  Irrawaddy  ( Burma ) , 
the  Menam  (Thailand),  and  the  Mekong  (Laos,  Cambodia,  and  South 
Vietnam ) ,  or  on  islands  such  as  Java  and  Luzon.  In  each  case  the  cluster 
serves  as  the  core  area  of  a  national  entity.  With  the  possible  exception 
of  Java,  the  particular  ecumenes  are  so  overshadowed  by  the  two  giant 
clusters  in  East  Asia— China  and  India— that  there  is  little  chance  for 
the  organization  of  an  independent  political  power  in  the  area. 

Dry  Asia.  This  vast  area,  the  traditional  domain  of  the  Moslem  religion, 
has  minor  population  centers  in  Egypt  and  the  Levant,  in  the  valley  of 
the  Tigris  and  Euphrates  (Iraq),  in  Iran,  in  Soviet  Asia,  and  even  in 
Chinese  Sinkiang.  In  the  past  this  vast  area  has  served  as  the  geographical 
base  for  empires  founded  on  the  mobility  of  the  nomadic  horseman.  To- 
day, however,  its  unity  lies  more  in  the  spiritual  cohesiveness  offered  by 
the  Moslem  religion,  and  to  a  lesser  extent  by  the  community  of  Turkic 
languages  spoken  all  the  way  from  Constantinople  to  five  hundred  miles 
inside  the  boundaries  of  China.  The  area  has  proven  too  fragmented  to 
provide  the  base  for  a  great  power  in  the  modern  world. 

URBAN  CONCENTRATIONS 

In  the  previous  sections  attention  has  been  called  to  the  importance  of 
a  strong  core  area  or  ecumene  to  the  internal  strength  and  organization  of 
the  modern  state.  Related  to  the  importance  of  the  core  area  is  the  degree 
of  urbanization  and  metropolitan  concentration.  The  core  area  is  usually 
dominated  by  the  capital  which  is  in  the  purest  sense  of  the  word  the 
"metro-pole"  and  often  the  cultural  hearth  of  the  nation.  Such  cities  as 
London,  Paris,  and  Rome  are  much  more  than  the  largest  cities  in  their  re- 
spective countries.  In  a  sense  they  are  England,  France,  and  Italy,  and  one 
cannot  think  of  these  countries  as  existing  without  these  home  cities.  The 
five  counties  surrounding  London  are  even  called  the  "home"  counties. 
There  is  a  universal  tendency  for  these  great  economic  and  cultural  cen- 
ters to  attract  a  larger  and  larger  proportion  of  the  total  population. 

Obviously  something  so  important  in  the  lives  of  many  millions  of 
people  as  the  growth  of  cities  and  the  urban  way  of  life  must  have  its 
effect  on  the  power  and  the  strategic  vulnerability  of  the  nations  involved. 
Such  concentration  of  population  has  often  been  regarded  as  affecting  the 


POPULATION  GROWTH  AND  PRESSURE  307 

internal  stability  of  the  state.  In  the  atomic  age  it  must  be  presumed  that 
external  vulnerability  is  likewise  affected  by  this  development. 

URBANIZATION  AND  POLITICAL  STABILITY 

The  theory  that  cities  are  a  source  of  instability  and  weakness  is  at  least 
as  old  as  Thomas  Jefferson  and  as  new  as  Communist  revolutionary  doc- 
trine. The  mobs  of  Paris  during  the  French  Revolution  have  left  a  pro- 
found effect  on  the  political  thought  of  the  Western  world.  Later,  Marx 
found  in  the  cities  the  apotheosis  of  capitalism  with  its  division  between 
pyramided  wealth  and  propertyless  proletariat.  In  the  present  century 
Oswald  Spengler  pictured  the  metropolis  as  the  ultimate  graveyard  of 
Western  civilization. 

In  the  long  sweep  of  history  it  may  be  that  modern  urban  society  is 
insufficiently  stable  to  provide  the  enduring  social  institutions  and  cultural 
traditions  necessary  for  a  lasting  civilization.  But  in  the  short  run,  it  is 
clear  that  those  who  fear  the  urban  mobs  as  revolutionary  forces  have 
been  refuted  by  recent  history.  The  most  urbanized  countries  are  at  the 
same  time  the  most  stable  politically.  The  twelve  countries  having  one- 
fourth  or  more  of  their  people  in  cities  of  a  hundred  thousand  or  over  is 
a  roster  of  countries  that  have  been  characterized  by  stable  governments 
since  World  War  II.  The  single  exception  is  Argentina. 

TABLE  9-1 
Degree  of  Urbanization:  Per  Cent  of  Population  Living  in  Cities 


CITIES  OF  100,000 

URBAN  AREAS  BY 

AND  OVER 

NATIONAL  DEFINITION  a 

Australia,  1947 

51.4 

68.9 

United  Kingdom,  1951 

51.0 

80.2 

United  States,  1950 

43.7 

63.7 

Argentina,  1947 

40.6 

62.5 

Israel,  1951 

39.9 

77.5 

Canada,  1951 

36.7 

62.1 

Netherlands,  1947 

35.2 

54.6 

Denmark,  1950 

33.5 

67.3 

New  Zealand,  1951 

32.8 

61.3 

Austria,  1951 

32.8 

49.1 

Western  Germany,  1950 

27.1  b 

71.1 

Belgium,  1947 

25.8 

62.7 

Japan,  1950 

25.6 

37.5 

a  National  definitions  of  urban  areas  vary  with  administrative  practices  in  the  countries  concerned  and 
are  therefore  unreliable  as  a  measure  of  urbanization.  To  take  an  extreme  illustration,  according  to  its  own 
definitions,  which  include  as  urban  all  persons  in  communities  of  500  or  over,  Iceland  is  71.7  per  cent 
urban  and  one  of  the  most  urbanized  countries  in  the  world. 

b  Excludes  Western  sector  of  Berlin. 

Source:   United  Nations,   Demographic   Yearbook,  1952   (New  York,   1953),  Table  B,  p.   11. 


308  HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 

Conspicuously  absent  from  this  list  are  France,  Italy,  and  Southern  and 
Eastern  European  countries,  many  of  which  have  experienced  great  politi- 
cal instability  over  the  last  fifty  years. 

If  we  take  the  other  end  of  the  scale,  those  nations  having  less  than 
10  per  cent  of  their  populations  in  large  cities,  the  list  generally  includes 
countries  that  have  not  been  characterized  by  great  political  stability: 
Bulgaria,  Burma,  Ceylon,  Colombia,  Dominican  Republic,  El  Salvador, 
Haiti,  India,  Iran,  Rumania,  Turkey,  and  Yugoslavia.  There  are  conspicu- 
ous exceptions,  such  as  Turkey. 

It  is  fair  to  say  that  in  the  modern  world  internal  political  stability  is 
more  likely  to  be  found  with  a  high  degree  of  urbanization  than  in  a 
peasant  economy  and  society.  It  is  precisely  the  countries  undergoing 
transition  from  the  old  self-contained  rural  peasant  world  that  are  experi- 
encing the  most  acute  political  disorder.  Since  European  techniques  and 
aspirations  have  now  penetrated  to  every  country  of  the  world,  there  are 
very  few  if  any  remaining  peasant  societies  living  in  premodern  pattern 
oblivious  to  the  disruptive  influences  of  Western  civilization. 

EXTERNAL  VULNERABILITY  OF  METROPOLISES 

It  is  easy  to  draw  a  quick  and  superficial  conclusion  that  the  things  that 
make  a  country  effective  in  terms  of  internal  organization  (such  as  cen- 
tralization in  urban  concentrations )  are  precisely  the  things  likely  to  make 
it  most  vulnerable  to  modern  warfare.  Thus  the  existence  of  strong  core 
areas  focused  in  metropolitan  conurbations  is  associated  with  internal 
stability,  but  this  source  of  strength  would  seem  to  make  the  countries 
concerned  more  vulnerable  to  air  and  atomic  attack. 

The  problem  is  probably  not  so  simple  and  certainly  is  as  yet  unsolved. 
In  the  old  days  of  slow  military  campaigns  overland,  the  vulnerability  of 
metropolitan  capitals  and  of  core  areas  could  be  crucial.  Except  for  the 
largest  countries  this  is  less  relevant  now  since  the  scope  of  warfare  is  so 
broad  that  the  population  and  industrial  concentrations  in  the  smaller 
countries  may  be  important  only  in  relation  to  larger  continental  entities. 
In  other  words,  it  is  now  not  so  much  the  national  ecumene  that  counts 
as  the  larger  continental  ecumene. 

Again  a  nation  with  fewer  urban  centers  may  in  fact  be  more  vulnerable 
than  one  with  many.  The  degree  and  diversification  of  industry  in  such 
countries  as  the  United  States  and  the  U.S.S.R.  is  reflected  in  the  existence 
of  a  great  many  urban  concentrations.  While  these  concentrations  contain 
a  relatively  large  percentage  of  total  populations,  they  also  represent 


POPULATION  GROWTH  AND  PRESSURE  309 

widely  dispersed  industrial  strength.  It  is  not  at  all  clear  that  the  United 
Kingdom  for  example,  with  forty-two  conurbations  of  over  a  hundred 
thousand  is  actually  more  vulnerable  to  complete  disorganization  from 
atomic  attack  than  France  with  twenty-two. 

C.    Growth 
WORLD  POPULATION  GROWTH 

One  of  the  most  distinctive  features  of  our  age  is  the  rapid  multiplica- 
tion of  our  species,  homo  sapiens. 

The  present  growth  of  world  population  is  unique  in  human  history. 
This  can  be  painfully  demonstrated  from  bits  of  historical  evidence.  A 
little  simple  arithmetic  will  show  it  to  be  true.  The  present  annual  world 
population  growth  is  estimated  at  well  over  30  million  and  perhaps  as  high 
as  40  million  a  year.  Had  this  amount  of  growth  continued  throughout  the 
Christian  era,  there  would  now  be  6.8  billions  of  us  rather  than  the  actual 
figure  of  about  2.6  billion.  At  the  present  rate  of  growth  (which  is  esti- 
mated to  be  at  least  1.2  per  year)  the  entire  population  of  the  globe  would 
be  descended  from  a  single  couple  living  at  the  time  of  Christ.  An  Argen- 
tinian demographer  has  carried  the  illustration  to  its  logical  conclusion: 
if  the  population  of  two  living  in  the  Garden  of  Eden  some  six  thousand 
years  ago  had  increased  on  the  average  of  one  per  cent  per  year  the  pres- 
ent human  population  would  be  so  vast  that  it  would  have  standing  room 
only,  not  just  on  the  surface  of  the  earth  but  on  the  surface  of  a  sphere 
with  a  radius  fourteen  times  the  orbit  of  the  planet  Neptune. 

Obviously  the  amount  of  current  population  growth  could  never  have 
existed  before;  and  the  present  rate  of  growth  could  have  existed  only  in 
brief  periods  of  man's  history. 

Population  growth  affects  political  geography  in  two  ways :  ( 1 )  it  never 
is  exactly  the  same  in  any  two  countries,  hence  the  demographic  bases  of 
political  power  are  always  changing;  ( 2 )  it  creates  increased  competition 
for  the  scarce  resources  of  the  earth.  The  first  views  people  as  a  source  of 
power  and  production,  the  second  as  consumers  who  must  be  fed.  These 
two  influences  often  work  against  each  other.  A  larger  population  may  be 
useful  as  a  source  of  increased  manpower.  At  the  same  time  more  people 
mean  more  competition  for  scarce  resources.  Population  growth  may 
cause  a  lower  level  of  living  than  might  be  attained  with  a  smaller  popu- 
lation. 

In  this  section  and  the  following  one  on  Structure,  we  will  deal  with 
population  as  a  source  of  power.  In  another  section,  on  Pressure,  we  will 


310  HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 

consider  measures  of  population  pressure,  and  the  extent  to  which  it  is  a 
real  as  against  a  rationalized  cause  of  political  conflict. 

Population  growth  is  often  overlooked  as  a  factor  in  redistribution  of 
political  power  because  its  course  is  steady,  undramatic,  and  persistent 
rather  than  immediate  and  self-evident.  Yet  in  the  longer  sweep  of  history 
different  rates  of  population  growth  have  been  associated  with  major 
changes  in  the  distribution  of  world  power.  There  has  been  an  enormous 
population  growth  in  every  major  region  of  the  world  in  the  modern  era, 
but  this  growth  has  occurred  very  unequally  among  the  several  continents. 

The  expansion  of  world  population  between  1650  and  1950  is  shown  in 
Table  9-2. 

TABLE  9-2 

World  Population  Growth,  1650-1950  * 
( in  Millions ) 


GROWTH 

APPROXIMATE 

1650 

1950 

1650-1950 

MULTIPLIER 

Asia 

330 

1320 

990 

4 

j  Europe 

100 

393 

493 

6 

I  U.S.S.R. 

200 

Africa 

100 

198 

98 

2 

Latin  America 

12 

165 

153 

14 

North  America 

1 

165 

164 

165 

Oceania 

2 

13 

11 

6 

World  Total 

545 

2454 

1909 

A)i 

*  Figures  for  1650  estimated  by  A.  M.  Carr-Saunders,  World  Population  (Oxford,  1936),  p.  42.  Figures 
for  1950  from  United  Nations  Demographic  Yearbook,  1953.  All  figures  for  1650  and  those  for  Asia  and 
Africa  in  1950  are  highly  proximate. 

Now,  as  in  all  previous  epochs,  Asia  is  the  principal  home  of  mankind. 
In  the  three  centuries  of  the  modern  era  the  Asian  population  has  grown 
by  a  billion  people. 

The  dynamic  demographic  element  in  modern  history,  however,  has 
been  the  expansion  of  Europe. 


THE  EXPANSION  OF  EUROPE 

The  population  of  the  home  continent  has  multiplied  six  times.  In  addi- 
tion some  200  million  persons  of  European  extraction  are  living  overseas. 
The  Europeans  have  thus  multiplied  some  eight  times  in  the  past  three 
centuries.  This  represents  an  increase  from  about  a  hundred  million  in 
1650  to  approximately  800  million  persons  of  European  extraction  living 


POPULATION  GROWTH  AND  PRESSURE  311 

in  the  world  at  the  present  time/'  The  population  of  European  descent  has 
increased  from  less  than  one-fifth  of  the  world's  people  in  1650  to  one- 
third  in  1950. 

The  expansion  of  Europe  relative  to  the  rest  of  the  world  has  not  pro- 
ceeded evenly  throughout  the  modern  era.  In  the  broadest  sense  the 
European  settlement  area  comprises  Europe,  the  Soviet  Union,  the  Ameri- 
cas, and  Oceania.  Growth  in  this  half  of  the  world  may  be  compared  with 
Asia  and  Africa  in  which  continents  Europeans  are  nowhere  a  majority. 
The  comparative  growth  in  these  two  areas  is  shown  in  Figure  9-5. 

The  population  growth  of  Europe  gained  momentum  in  the  late  eight- 
eenth century  and  after  1800  grew  relatively  much  faster  than  in  the  rest 
of  the  world.  Between  1800  and  1920  the  population  of  the  European 
settlement  area  gained  markedly  on  that  of  Asia  and  Africa.  Since  1920, 
however,  two  things  have  happened:  (1)  the  rates  of  growth  in  the  Euro- 
pean settlement  area  have  slowed;  (2)  the  populations  of  Asia  and  Africa 
have  taken  a  forward  spurt. 

Estimates  made  by  United  Nations  experts  for  population  growth  in  the 
future  suggest  the  continuation  of  these  trends  reversing  those  of  the  last 
150  years.  If  anything,  Asia- Africa  will  contain  a  rising  share  of  the  rapidly 
increasing  population  projected  for  the  next  generation. 

Let  us  examine  the  demographic  expansion  of  Europe,  and  the  signifi- 
cance of  the  reversal  of  this  trend  that  now  seems  in  the  offing. 

Population  growth  of  European  peoples  has  been  part  and  parcel  of  the 
extension  of  European  political  and  cultural  hegemony  in  the  world.  The 
population  of  Europe  has  expanded  three  ways : 

5  The  population  of  predominantly  European  descent  in  the  world  may  be  computed 
as  follows.  In  addition  to  the  population  of  Europe  west  of  the  Soviet  Union,  approxi- 
mately 165  million  of  the  200  million  inhabitants  of  the  U.S.S.R.  in  1950  belonged  to 
nationalities  commonly  regarded  as  European.  Of  the  remaining  35  million  perhaps 
the  majority. live  wholly  or  partly  within  the  physical  confines  of  Europe  but  are  not 
conventionally  regarded  as  of  European  culture.  The  deduction  of  some  15  million 
non-whites  from  the  165  million  inhabitants  of  North  America  provides  an  estimate 
of  150  million  of  European  stock  in  that  continent.  There  are  somewhat  over  10 
million  persons  of  European  descent  in  Oceania. 

It  is  impossible  to  set  a  precise  figure  to  the  number  of  persons  of  predominantly 
European  descent  in  Latin  America.  A  generalization  of  careful  analysis  made  in  this 
field  indicates  a  rough  division  as  follows:  One-third  75  per  cent  or  more  white,  one- 
third  mestizo,  one-sixth  Indian,  and  one-sixth  Negroid,  the  latter  including  all  persons 
with  identifiable  Negroid  blood.  There  are  perhaps  5  million  persons  of  European 
descent  living  in  Africa  and  Asia.  Thus  the  European  population  of  the  world  in  1950 
may  be  summed  up  as  follows:  Europe,  393  million;  U.S.S.R.,  165  million;  North 
America,  150  million;  Latin  America,  55  million;  Oceania,  10  million;  Africa  and  Asia, 
5  million.  This  provides  an  estimated  world  total  of  778  million.  In  addition  there  are 
some  70  million  mestizos  and  mulattoes  in  the  Americas  and  an  unknown  number 
in  Africa  and  Asia. 


312  HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 

More  Intensive  Use  of  the  Home  Territory.  The  population  of  Europe 
west  of  Russia  has  increased  over  300  million  since  1650.  This  expansion 
reflects  both  more  intensive  agricultural  settlement  and  more  indus- 
trialization. 

It  is  often  forgotten  that  much  of  Europe  was  still  a  frontier  well  into 
the  modern  era.  In  Roman  times  only  the  Mediterranean  littoral  was  fully 
settled  by  modern  standards.  By  the  Middle  Ages  the  line  of  mature  agri- 
cultural settlement  had  moved  northward  and  westward  to  include  France 
and  the  low  countries.  But  much  of  Germany  and  Eastern  Europe  re- 
mained at  an  early  stage  of  agricultural  settlement;  Northern  Europe  and 
the  Russian  plain  were  still  very  thinly  peopled.  By  the  seventeenth  cen- 
tury the  "frontier"  had  moved  far  to  the  east  and  into  the  remote  north, 
but  there  was  still  much  unused  land.  Reclamation  and  settlement  of  these 
lands  contributed  to  the  more  rapid  growth  of  northwest  and  eastern 
Europe  as  compared  with  the  Mediterranean  countries. 

Later,  great  commercial  and  industrial  development  enabled  these  re- 
gions to  gain  political  and  economic  leadership  in  Europe— an  accession  of 
power  made  possible  by  the  strengthening  of  the  agricultural  base  and  by 
earlier  increases  of  population  attendant  on  the  mature  settlement  of  the 
region. 

The  Settlement  of  the  East.  The  domination  of  the  Russian  plain  by  the 
Tatars  was  effectively  crushed  about  the  time  of  Columbus.  The  border, 
or  "Ukrain"  moved  forward  into  the  rich  black  earth  of  the  country  so 
named.  From  their  forests  around  Moscow  the  Russians  moved  out  across 
the  rich  plains  forbidden  them  earlier  by  their  defenselessness  against  the 
horsemen  of  Central  Asia.  There  followed  Russian  feats  of  exploration 
and  settlement  similar  to  those  of  the  American  West.  Eastern  Europe 
was  still  being  "settled"  in  the  eighteenth  and  nineteenth  centuries  and 
parts  of  European  and  Asiatic  Russia  even  in  the  twentieth  century.  Large 
sections  of  steppe-land  in  the  North  Caucasus  and  Central  Asia  were  first 
turned  by  the  plow  under  the  Communist  regime.  The  eastward  tide  of 
settlement  in  Russia  paralleled  our  own  "westward  movement." 

The  eastward  movement  in  Russia  resulted  in  the  settlement  of  enor- 
mous areas  by  Europeans,  areas  now  occupied  by  as  many  as  a  hundred 
million  of  their  descendants.  The  impetus  has  expanded  the  boundaries 
of  European  influence  effectively  not  only  from  the  Don,  which  used  to  be 
regarded  as  the  eastward  edge  of  Europe,  to  the  Urals  and  the  Caucasus 
mountains,  and  beyond  into  Siberia  and  Central  Asia.  Much  of  Asiatic 
Russia  is  still  not  effectively  occupied  by  Europeans  (or  by  any  other 
race). 


POPULATION  GROWTH  AND  PRESSURE  313 

The  frontier  psychology  of  the  Soviet  Union  is  probably  one  of  the 
factors  which  explain  Soviet  expansionism."  One  may  find  parallels  in  the 
"manifest  destiny"  of  the  United  States,  so  popular  a  phrase  in  American 
expansion  during  the  last  century.7  But  as  in  our  own  Western  movement 
the  yearning  for  land  is  no  longer  so  compelling  as  the  exploitation  of  new 
industries,  of  mining,  and  of  forestry  in  the  new  regions. 

The  Settlement  of  Overseas  Areas.  Europeans  have  effectively  occupied 
(a)  most  of  the  habitable  territory  of  North  America  north  of  the  Rio 
Grande,  ( b )  the  temperate  zones  of  Latin  America,  including  Argentina, 
Uruguay,  and  Brazil  south  of  the  20th  parallel,  (c)  Australia  and  New 
Zealand.  White  or  mestizo  populations  are  also  in  majority  in  most  of 
Latin  America  with  two  exceptions:  first,  the  ancient  Amerindian  strong- 
holds in  the  highlands  of  Ecuador,  Bolivia,  Peru,  and  Paraguay;  and  sec- 
ond, the  British  and  French  West  Indies  which  were  chiefly  peopled  from 
Africa.  Other  than  within  the  Russian  orbit,  Europeans  have  nowhere 
colonized  Asia  unless  Israel  may  be  regarded  as  a  European  settlement. 
Only  in  French  North  Africa  and  in  South  Africa  are  there  substantial 
footholds  of  European  settlement  on  that  continent.  But  in  both  cases 
Europeans  are  greatly  outnumbered.  In  French  North  Africa  there  are 
about  one  and  a  half  million  as  against  approximately  18  million  Moslems. 
In  the  Union  of  South  Africa  there  were  2.6  million  Europeans  in  1950 
as  against  10  million  non-Europeans. 

It  would  be  idle  to  suggest  that  the  relative  expansion  of  European 
peoples  was  in  itself  the  explanation  or  the  exclusive  means  of  the  exten- 
sion of  European  civilization  throughout  the  world.  It  is  not  always 
certain  which  is  cause  and  which  is  effect.  Did  population  growth  in 
Europe  both  stimulate  and  enable  the  political  expansion  of  Europe  or 
did  the  political  expansion  of  Europe  provide  the  means  for  the  rapid 
population  growth  of  Europe?  Both  are  undoubtedly  true. 

It  is  clear  that  the  industrialization  of  Europe  and  its  rapid  population 
growth  was  in  part  stimulated  by  access  to  raw  materials  and  markets  in 
overseas  countries.  At  the  same  time  rapid  population  growth  provided 
both  the  sinews  and  the  motives  for  colonization  and  imperialist  expan- 
sion. One  thing  is  certain:  the  firmest  influence  of  European  expansion  is 
in  those  areas  that  were  colonized  and  populated  by  persons  of  European 
stock.  The  European  civilization  is  now  spreading  very  rapidly  to  all 
people  and  to  all  parts  of  the  world,  but  the  most  complete  migration  of 

6  See  the  discussion  of  the  Russian  urge  to  the  sea  as  a  source  of  expansion,  pp. 
243  ff. 

7  See  pp.  10-12. 


314  HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 

European  culture  to  other  continents  has  been  in  those  areas  colonized 
by  Europeans  themselves. 

POPULATION  AND  POWER  IN  EUROPE 

The  larger  aspects  of  the  expansion  of  European  population  have  also 
been  reflected  in  the  specific  political  history  of  the  dominant  countries 
in  the  European  continent  and  the  European  settlement  area.  In  the  fol- 
lowing paragraphs,  attention  will  be  directed  toward  the  demographic 
base  for  the  successive  primacy  in  European  settlement  areas  of  France, 
Germany,  Britain,  Russia,  and  the  United  States  (cf.  Fig.  9-3). 

France.  Much  of  the  history  of  Europe  between  1650  and  1800,  re- 
volves around  France  as  the  leading  power  of  Europe.  She  was  the 
wealthiest  and  in  many  respects  the  most  advanced  country  in  Europe. 
In  the  seventeenth  and  early  eighteenth  centuries  France  probably  had 
the  largest  population  in  Europe,  not  even  excluding  Russia,  which  now 
has  five  times  the  population  of  France.  This  population  served  as  a  firm 
basis  for  French  hegemony  in  Europe  and  for  the  Napoleonic  conquests. 
But  by  1800  Russia  had  passed  France  in  population,  and  the  massive 
size  and  population  of  that  country  finally  destroyed  French  hopes  for 
complete  mastery  of  Europe. 

The  economic  and  political  position  of  France  in  Europe  has  changed 
enormously  since  1800.  One  element  in  this  change  is  the  fact  that  France 
now  stands  fifth  rather  than  first  in  population  size.  She  had  been  passed 
by  both  Germany  and  the  United  States  by  1870-1871  when  she  suffered 
military  defeat  at  the  hands  of  the  Germans;  the  United  Kingdom  passed 
France  around  1900,  or  if  one  includes  the  European  population  of  the 
Dominions,  the  British  population  surpassed  the  French  about  1885;  and 
Italy  passed  France  about  1930.  In  1939  France  had  only  7.3  per  cent  of 
Europe's  people  as  compared  with  about  15  per  cent  in  1800. 

Germany.  The  rise  of  Germany  likewise  has  demographic  foundations. 
In  the  Napoleonic  period,  Germans  lived  in  a  Europe  dominated  not  only 
politically  but  also  numerically  by  the  French.  As  the  result  of  the  eco- 
nomic development  of  Germany  and  the  population  increase  made  pos- 
sible by  this  development,  since  the  middle  of  the  last  century  Germans 
have  become  much  the  most  numerous  of  the  European  peoples  aside 
from  the  Russians.  As  the  largest  single  group,  occupying  a  central  posi- 
tion in  Europe,  it  is  natural  that  the  Germans  should  have  sought  to  bring 
the  balance  of  political  power  into  line  with  their  growing  numerical  and 
industrial  importance.  That  this  might  have  been  achieved  more  effec- 


POPULATION  GROWTH  AND  PRESSURE 


315 


POPULATION  GROWTH    1800-1949 

MILLIONS  OF  INHABITANTS 
200 


150 

100 
80 

60 

40 


20 


10 
8 


..• 

..."- 



.•" 

,..•- 

.•"■* 

•  UNITED  STATES 

USi 

**** 

,« 

...-• 

.* 

*^' 

-^ 

••* 

•^ 

**"' 

GERA 

\ANY 

—  "^ 

*  *"  ^Tt 

— - 

^ 

—  *' 

• 

•• 

• 

FRANCE. 
UNITED  KINGDOM 

st*^H 

••"if, 

M.Y 

*>*' 

+' 

' 

...-••■ 

• 

•*UNI 

• 

TEDS 

rATES 

• 
• 

• 

• 

•* 

SE* 

l-LOG 

\RITR 

VMCSC 

ALE 

1800  1810  1820  1830  1840  1850  1860  1870  1880  1890  1900  1910  1920  1930  1940  1950 

Fig.  9-3. 


tively  through  peaceful  rather  than  through  warlike  means  is  now  unfor- 
tunately beside  the  point. 

By  virtue  of  its  more  rapid  natural  increase  and  the  Nazi  annexation  of 
German-speaking  areas,  Germany  in  1939  had  80  millions  or  twice  the 
population  of  France  and  a  considerably  larger  population  than  that  of 
Britain. 

Soviet  Union.  The  populations  of  Eastern  Europe  have  grown  faster 
than  those  of  Western  Europe.  At  an  earlier  period  the  large  population 
growth  of  this  region  was  made  possible  by  the  fact  that  great  areas  were 
then  in  the  process  of  initial  agricultural  settlement,  or,  put  in  other  terms, 
in  transition  from  a  pastoral  to  a  settled  farm  economy. 

This  agricultural  settlement  represented  a  superior  form  of  land  utiliza- 


316  HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 

tion,  and  made  possible  the  support  of  a  far  denser  population  than  had 
formerly  existed.  More  recently  the  wave  of  material  progress  represented 
by  industrialization  and  an  urban  way  of  life  has  reached  Eastern  Europe 
from  its  centers  of  origin  in  the  West.  In  Russia  the  contrast  of  the  old  and 
the  new  resulted  in  such  severe  stress  on  the  old  social  order  that  it  was 
swept  away  and  the  new  technical  civilization  was  ushered  in  with  an 
impetus  unexampled  in  history. 

These  developments  have  made  possible  rapid  population  increase  such 
as  existed  in  Western  Europe  at  an  earlier  period.  Despite  war  and  revo- 
lution, which  apparently  cost  Russia  a  total  population  deficit  of  26  mil- 
lions, including  both  deaths  and  loss  of  births,  between  1900  and  1943 
the  population  of  the  territory  of  the  Soviet  Union  grew  more  rapidly  than 
that  of  Western  Europe. 

The  very  large  total  figure  for  the  Soviet  population  conceals  the  cos- 
mopolitan character  of  the  Soviet  Union,  in  which  there  are  some  seventy 
official  languages.  Only  comparatively  recently,  probably  within  the  last 
thirty  years,  has  the  Great  Russian  surpassed  the  German  as  the  largest 
linguistic  group  in  Europe.  The  1926  census  of  the  Soviet  Union  reported 
78  million  persons  of  Great  Russian  ethnic  group.  At  about  the  same  time, 
as  reported  in  various  national  censuses,  there  were  85  million  ethnic 
Germans  in  Europe. 

By  1939  there  were  reported  to  be  99  million  persons  of  Great  Russian 
"nationality"  as  over  against  the  80  million  inhabitants  of  the  "Greater 
Reich." 

Today  the  German  minorities  of  the  East  are  liquidated.  The  two  Ger- 
manies  together  contain  about  70  million:  (50  in  the  Federal  Republic, 
18  in  East  Germany,  and  2  in  West  Berlin).  The  U.S.S.R.  now  has  about 
200  million  people  of  which  slightly  over  half  are  Great  Russians.  The 
demographic  balance  has  clearly  swung  in  favor  of  the  latter.  This  is  the 
demographic  basis  for  the  eastward  shift  of  power  in  Europe. 

Thinking  in  terms  of  the  European  settlement  area  as  a  whole  there  has 
of  course  also  been  a  westward  migration  of  people  and  power. 

The  United  Kingdom.  Allied  to  the  demographic  expansion  of  Germany 
and  of  Northwest  Europe  has  been  that  of  Britain.  Its  growth  has  matched 
and  if  anything  exceeded  that  of  the  Germans.  But  much  more  of  the 
British  population  increase  was  drained  off  overseas;  it  established  the 
British  Dominions  and  it  contributed  the  largest  element  in  the  population 
of  the  United  States.  While  the  United  Kingdom  has  always  had  a  smaller 
population  in  its  island  home  than  that  of  the  German-speaking  areas  of 


POPULATION  GROWTH  AND  PRESSURE  317 

Central  Europe,  this  metropolitan  population  has  been  effectively  bol- 
stered in  influence  both  by  the  tremendous  resources  of  the  Empire  and 
by  the  European  population  of  the  Dominions.  If  only  the  latter  are  con- 
sidered as  contributing  to  the  demographic  weight  of  the  British  popula- 
tion, this  nevertheless  provides  a  demographic  base  comparable  to  that 
of  Germany.  In  1939  this  larger  "British"  population  amounted  to  70  mil- 
lion and  at  the  present  time  it  has  risen  to  80  million  and  is  thus  more 
numerous  than  the  population  of  a  united  Germany. 

The  European  and  especially  British  populations  that  settled  the  United 
States  and  the  British  Dominions  increased  even  more  rapidly  in  the  new 
environment  than  they  did  in  the  countries  from  which  they  came.  It  was 
this  rapid  growth  in  the  United  States,  even  more  than  migration,  that 
brought  about  the  enormous  expansion  of  the  American  population.  In 
the  early  nineteenth  century  the  average  American  woman  surviving 
through  the  childbearing  period  had  eight  children.  It  was  this  great  fer- 
tility that  brought  about  an  average  growth  of  25  per  cent  per  decade 
even  when,  as  between  1800  and  1840,  there  was  comparatively  little 
immigration  from  Europe. 

No  one  can  say  what  proportion  of  the  American  population  is  de- 
scended from  British  stock,  since  there  has  been  a  wide  mingling  of 
European  nationalities.  In  1940,  ninety-three  million  or  71  per  cent  of  the 
population  were  estimated  to  be  of  European  origin  and  of  English  mother 
tongue,  but  this  figure  doubtless  includes  a  great  many  persons  wholly  or 
in  part  descended  from  other  European  stocks. 

Through  this  rapid  natural  growth  and  by  virtue  of  cultural  assimilation 
of  other  European  and  African  nationalities,  the  world  population  of  Eng- 
lish mother  tongue  has  grown  from  perhaps  20  million  in  1800  to  some 
225  million,  leaving  aside  the  wide  use  of  English  as  a  language  of  com- 
merce, government,  and  higher  education  by  persons  of  other  native 
tongues.  Whether  in  demographic  or  cultural  terms  this  has  been  the 
most  phenomenal  national  expansion  in  modern  times. 

As  is  now  widely  recognized,  the  European  population,  and  especially 
that  living  in  the  heartlands  of  Western  Europe,  is  not  increasing  as  rap- 
idly as  it  formerly  did.  As  a  result  of  the  differential  growth  of  the  three 
great  divisions  of  the  European  settlement  area,  the  mantle  of  political 
supremacy  has  passed  from  the  original  homeland  to  the  two  great  periph- 
eral areas,  one  westward  overseas  and  the  other  eastward  in  the  great 
land  mass  of  the  Eurasian  plain.  On  the  horizon  is  the  prospective  great 
expansion  of  the  Asian  peoples. 


318  HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 

In  order  to  understand  the  basis  for  these  great  changes,  both  historical 
and  future,  it  is  necessary  to  analyze  the  dynamics  of  human  population. 
These  have  followed  a  cycle  of  development  that  is  sometimes  called  the 
"Vital  Revolution." 

THE  VITAL  REVOLUTION 

Accompanying  the  Industrial  Revolution  has  been  a  profound  change 
in  man's  biological  balance  with  his  environment.  In  its  initial  phases  this 
has  been  the  increasing  ability  of  man  to  cope  with  the  age-old  scourges 
of  the  four  dread  horsemen  of  the  Apocalypse— famine,  pestilence,  war, 
and  death. 

First,  the  establishment  of  national  states  imposed  public  order  and 
thereby  greatly  increased  personal  security  from  the  dangers  of  civil 
strife,  personal  vendettas,  and  deaths  from  such  mundane  incidents  as 
highway  robbery,  personal  violence,  and  criminal  negligence.  Then  the 
state  increasingly  assumed  responsibility  for  the  welfare  of  its  citizens- 
through  free  public  education,  through  elementary  public  health  meas- 
ures, and  more  recently  through  social  security  provisions  and  institutions. 
These,  as  well  as  scientific  advances,  brought  about  the  reductions  in 
deaths  achieved  in  the  more  advanced  countries  of  Western  Europe  dur- 
ing the  eighteenth  and  nineteenth  centuries. 

At  the  same  time  the  agricultural  and  industrial  revolutions  provided 
the  basis  for  a  rise  in  the  level  of  living  for  the  mass  of  the  people.  In 
practical  terms,  this  meant  better  nutrition,  clothing,  housing,  and  new 
standards  of  personal  cleanliness,  all  of  which  tended  to  reduce  the  death 
rate.  Finally  and  really  very  recently,  medical  research  has  found  an- 
swers to  many  serious  diseases  that  could  not  previously  be  controlled  by 
the  usual  public  health  procedures. 

Altogether  these  measures  have  made  possible  the  doubling  of  the 
average  expectation  of  life  at  birth.  For  Europeans  and  Americans  this 
expectation  is  twenty  years  longer  than  in  our  grandparents'  generation, 
and  forty  years  longer  than  in  seventeenth  century  Europe.  This  is  perhaps 
the  greatest  material  achievement  of  our  civilization. 

Recently  in  the  more  advanced  countries  of  the  world  there  has  been 
a  parallel  decline  in  the  birth  rate.  But  this  decline  in  births  has  come 
later  than  the  reduction  of  deaths— hence  the  unique  population  growth 
that  is  well-nigh  universal  today.  It  is  natural  that  a  decline  in  the  birth 
rate  should  follow  rather  than  precede  the  decline  of  the  death  rate  in 
demographic  evolution. 


POPULATION  GROWTH  AND  PRESSURE  319 

From  time  immemorial,  human  beings  have  had  the  strongest  biologi- 
cal, social,  and  even  religious  compulsions  to  "increase  and  multiply." 
These  compulsions  have  evoked  persistently  high  birth  rates  throughout 
the  world.  Such  reproduction  was  costly  in  terms  of  human  wastage, 
since  a  large  proportion  of  those  born  failed  to  achieve  maturity.  But  high 
birth  rates  were  necessary  if  the  race  was  to  survive  the  perils  of  life  in 
previous  ages. 

The  West.  About  one-third  of  the  human  race  now  exercises  a  substan- 
tial degree  of  voluntary  control  of  family  size.  In  a  number  of  European 
countries  this  reduction  of  births  had  reached  a  point  before  World  War 
II  at  which  many  persons  both  in  Fascist  and  in  democratic  countries 
were  becoming  worried  about  the  possibility  of  race  suicide.  The  baby 
boom  following  the  war  dispelled  the  fears  that  people,  given  the  means 
of  voluntary  control  of  family  size,  will  necessarily  fail  to  reproduce  them- 
selves. In  fact,  the  wide  fluctuations  in  the  birth  rate  in  the  depression 
years,  during  the  war,  and  in  the  postwar  period  have  concealed  a  rather 
stable  average  family  size  in  the  West. 

What  matters  in  the  long  run,  of  course,  is  not  the  annual  birth  rate  but 
the  size  of  completed  families.  Recent  analysis  of  cohort  fertility— the  fer- 
tility of  women  born  in  the  same  years  and  passing  through  life  together 
—has  given  us  new  methods  for  analyzing  fertility  trends.  Among  white 
women  born  in  the  United  States,  in  five-year  periods  beginning  in  1900 
and  ending  in  1925,  the  average  number  of  children  per  woman  has  varied 
only  between  2.3  for  the  women  born  from  1905  to  1909  and  a  maximum 
of  2.7  for  those  born  from  1920  to  1924.  The  latter  women  of  course  have 
not  completed  their  normal  childbearing  years,  but  it  is  possible  to  make 
reasonable  estimates  of  their  final  fertility  performance  on  the  basis  of 
experience  thus  far.  These  data  indicate  that  the  actual  size  of  American 
families  has  not  changed  nearly  as  much  as  the  annual  birth  rates  might 
suggest. 

Similar  studies  in  Britain  suggest  that  the  number  of  children  per  mar- 
ried couple  has  remained  remarkably  stable  over  the  last  twenty-five  years 
at  about  2.2  children  per  couple. 

It  would  seem  that  the  industrial  West  is  moving  toward  a  new  and 
more  efficient  reproduction  in  which  low  birth  and  death  rates  are 
roughly  balanced  in  a  new  demographic  equilibrium.  There  is  every 
reason  to  suppose  that  the  huge  populations  of  the  underdeveloped  areas, 
given  the  opportunity,  will  respond  to  the  same  incentives  that  have 
brought  about  the  reductions  of  births  in  the  West.  Neither  ideology  nor 


320  HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 

great  cultural  barriers  have  stopped  the  decline  of  births  in  a  country 
once  modern  influences  have  reached  the  mass  of  the  people.  Let  us  illus- 
trate this,  first,  from  the  experience  of  Russia,  and  second,  from  the  expe- 
rience of  Japan. 

The  Soviet  Union.  The  categorical  anti-Malthusian  doctrines  of  Com- 
munism, backed  by  the  most  comprehensive  pro-natal  measures  existing 
in  the  world  today,  have  apparently  not  been  successful  in  checking  very 
rapid  declines  in  the  Russian  birth  rate  since  the  war.  Before  World  War 
II  the  Russians  were  temporarily  successful  in  checking  the  decline  of 
births  resulting  from  abortion  in  the  early  1930's.  This  success  was 
achieved  by  the  simple  expedient  of  closing  down  the  free  public  abortion 
clinics.  Since  the  war,  however,  the  supplements  to  family  wages  on  be- 
half of  children  and  the  "mother  heroine  medals"  seem  to  have  been  in- 
effective in  stopping  the  spread  of  the  small-family  pattern. 

According  to  its  official  statistics,  the  birth  rate  in  the  Soviet  Union  in 
1955  was  25.6  per  thousand  population  8  as  compared  with  24.6  in  the 
United  States.  The  Soviet  figure  represents  a  drastic  decline  from  the 
prewar  figure  of  38  per  thousand.  If  adjustment  is  made  for  the  concen- 
tration of  the  Russian  population  in  the  young  adult  ages,  the  current 
fertility  in  the  U.S.S.R.  must  be  substantially  below  that  in  the  United 
States. 

Japan.  The  case  of  Japan  also  reveals  the  extent  to  which  the  small 
family  pattern  may  cross  cultural  barriers.  Once  Japan  became  predomi- 
nantly urban  and  industrial,  the  traditional  forces  of  Oriental  familism  and 
ancestor  worship  apparently  failed  to  retard  the  decline  of  the  birth  rate. 
It  is  interesting  to  note  that  aside  from  fluctuations  in  the  birth  and  death 
rates  associated  with  wars,  the  pattern  of  vital  rates  in  Japan  during  the 
last  thirty-five  years  has  very  closely  approximated  the  trend  of  birth  and 
death  rates  in  England  forty  years  earlier  at  a  somewhat  comparable  stage 
of  industrialization.  By  1954  the  birth  rate  in  Japan  was  20.1,  well  below 
that  of  the  United  States  and  rapidly  approaching  European  levels. 

The  specific  means  used  to  restrict  family  size  may  differ  from  country 
to  country:  in  Ireland,  through  late  marriage;  in  Western  Europe,  gener- 
ally, by  birth  control;  in  Japan,  by  abortions,  which  Japanese  experts 
report  now  number  over  one  million  a  year,  despite  growing  efforts  by  the 
Japanese  government  to  introduce  less  drastic  methods  of  family  limi- 
tation; and  in  Puerto  Rico,  and  increasingly  elsewhere,  by  post-partum 
sterilization  of  women  in  hospitals,  at  the  request  of  the  women  concerned 
and  generally  following  the  delivery  of  their  fourth  or  fifth  child.  Wher- 

8  New  York  Times,  June  7,  1956. 


POPULATION  GROWTH  AND  PRESSURE  321 

ever  people  have  become  literate,  urbanized,  and  free  of  the  debilitating 
psychological  and  physical  effects  of  the  major  epidemic  diseases,  the 
birth  rate  has  declined. 


DEMOGRAPHIC  STAGES 

How  are  these  differing  stages  in  the  Vital  Revolution  actually  reflected 
in  population  trends  in  the  world  today?  In  its  analysis  of  this  problem  the 
UN  has  delineated  five  demographic  types,  illustrated  in  Figure  9-4.  The 
first  of  these  includes  those  countries  in  which  both  fertility  and  mortality 
are  low.  In  Western  Europe,  rates  of  population  growth  are  now 
generally  under  one  per  cent  per  year  and  the  lowest  for  any  major 
region  of  the  world.  English-speaking  countries  overseas  are  included  in 
this  category,  but  their  higher  fertility  and  higher  rates  of  growth,  ranging 
from  1.5  to  2  per  cent  per  year,  suggest  that  these  countries  are  some- 
what different  from  those  of  Western  Europe. 

Type  2  includes  those  areas  where  the  birth  rate  has  now  definitely 
begun  to  decline.  The  death  rate  is  now  low  in  these  regions.  This  situa- 
tion is  characteristic  of  Eastern  Europe,  the  Soviet  Union  and  temperate 
South  America.  Rates  of  population  growth  in  these  countries  range  be- 
tween 1.5  and  2  per  cent— that  is  to  say,  somewhat  lower  than  in  type  3. 

Type  3  includes  those  countries  that  have  not  moved  so  far  in  the 
demographic  transition.  In  these  areas,  which  chiefly  include  tropical 
America  and  South  Africa,  birth  rates  remain  very  high  but  death  rates 
are  now  at  fairly  low  levels.  These  areas  are  experiencing  the  most  rapid 
growth  observable  in  the  world  today,  generally  over  2  per  cent  per 
year. 

Type  4  includes  those  areas  in  which  mortality,  though  still  high,  is 
being  reduced,  while  fertility  remains  at  high  primitive  levels.  This  type 
characterizes  the  Middle  East,  the  Arab  world,  and  most  of  South  and 
East  Asia.  In  these  areas  population  growth  is  now  1  to  2  per  cent 
per  year  and  rising  as  deaths  are  increasingly  brought  under  control  by 
cheap  and  elementary  public  health  measures. 

Type  5,  characterized  by  primitive  levels  of  high  fertility  and  high 
mortality,  is  now  largely  restricted  to  the  native  population  of  black 
Africa.  Not  long  ago  in  human  history,  this  was  the  typical  demographic 
situation  of  mankind.  But  even  in  this  region  there  is  a  considerable  im- 
pact of  the  influences  bringing  about  the  Vital  Revolution,  especially  as 
regards  reduction  of  deaths. 


J= 

M) 

j: 

. — , 

e 

en 

o 

— 

« 

>s 

E 

•w 

t. 

^3 

o 

a 

'— 

•w 

c 

>h 

O 

S 

o 

s 

* 

^^ 

o 

CO 

^^ 

>, 

h 

>> 

"a 

T3 

— 

C 

0 

« 

E 

>> 

.= 

U) 

44 

>- 

— 

01 

-c 

c 

60 

CS 

C 

S 

— 

u 

0) 

4^ 

T3 

9) 

— 

<N 

— 

>* 

i5 

m 

05 

> . 

•w 

O 

>.' 

b 

— 

£ 

o 

c 

-o 

£ 

c 

bf) 

fl 

C 

X 

C 

4-> 

^^ 

u 

44 

u 

0) 

-s 

— 

-s 

> 

c 

cd 

O 

^ 

►» 

44 

1— 1 

7^ 

^—^ 

— 

SJ 

(44 

V 

a-= 

&■» 

BO 

H 

*— 

o 

> 

*— 

^r 

a 

^—' 

« 

•  r\ 

u 

> 

bli 

o 

li 

E 

cd 

01 

>- 

Q 

0 

E 

>-> 

,2 

? 

0 

C 

o 

>x 

M 

01 

B 

K 

— 

T3 

-a 
c 

La 

CS 

O 

£ 

"* 

e 

05 

144 

o 

H 

b 

322 


POPULATION  GROWTH  AND  PRESSURE 

WORLD  POPULATION  GROWTH  -  ACTUAL  16501950 
AND  UNITED  NATIONS    MEDIUM     ESTIMATES     1950-1980 


323 


MILLIONS  OF  INHABITANTS 


4,000 
3,500 

1 

1 

1 

1 

1 

1 

3,000 

I 

1 
1 

1 

1 

2,500 

1 
I 

1 

1 

world/ 

1 

2,000 

1 

1 

1 

1 

1 

/ 

ASIA  -  AFRICA./ 

/ 

/ 

1,000 

/ 

500 

EUROPEA 

N  SETTLEMENT  / 

.REA^X*^ 

O 

1650 


1700 


1750 


1800 


1850 


1900 


1950  1980        j.ft 


Fig.  9-5. 


FUTURE  POPULATIONS 

What  do  these  different  trends  mean  in  terms  of  future  populations? 

For  this  purpose  we  may  use  recent  forecasts  prepared  by  the  Popula- 
tion Division  of  the  United  Nations  relating  to  the  period  1950  to  1980. 
Figure  9-5  is  intended  to  give  historical  perspective  illustrating  the  mo- 
mentum and  acceleration  of  absolute  population  growth  in  the  world  and 


324 


HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 


POPULATION   GROWTH  IN  THE  WORLD  AND  ITS  MAJOR 
REGIONS-ACTUAL  1920-1950  AND  UNITED  NATIONS 
MEDIUM    ESTIMATES     1950-1980 


MILLIONS  OF  INHABITANTS 
4,000 


3,000 


2,000 


1,000 
900 
800 

700 

600 

500 
400 

300 


200 


100 
90 


SEMI-LOGARI' 

HMIC  SCALE 

^^ 

WORLD. 

---"" 

ASIA 

^^ 

^^ 

EASTERN  EU 

"^WESTERN   EU 

ROPE 

'^"~" '"  — 

^' 

AFRICA^--^ 
"^LATIN  AMERK 

:a 

*  ANGLO-AMERK 

:a 

1920 


1930 


1940 


1950 


1960 


1970 


1980 


IPC 


Fig.  9-6. 


its  two  great  subdivisions:  Asia-Africa  and  the  European  settlement  area, 
which  includes  Europe  and  the  U.S.S.R.,  the  Americas  and  Oceania.  Since 
1650  there  has  been  a  great  expansion  of  the  European  population.  In 
some  periods  this  has  exceeded  even  the  absolute  amount  of  growth  in 
Asia  and  Africa,  but  the  latter  area  has  never  lost  its  clear  predominance 
in  numbers.  Current  and  foreseeable  trends  will  widen  this  predominance. 
The  extent  of  this  divergence  will  depend  much  on  the  situation  in 


POPULATION  GROWTH  AND  PRESSURE  325 

China.  Until  very  recently  it  was  generally  accepted  that  the  population 
of  China  was  under  500  million  and  that  it  was  growing  little  if  at  all.  The 
United  Nations  estimates  incorporate  this  assumption  in  their  forecasts. 
But  recent  reports  from  the  first  modern  census  in  China,  taken  in  1953, 
indicate  a  population  of  not  500  million  but  close  to  600  million  increasing 
at  2  per  cent  per  year.  If  these  latter  figures  for  China  were  used  in  the 
projections,  the  world  estimate  for  1980  would  be  close  to  4  billion  rather 
than  the  3.6  billion  shown  on  this  chart. 

Figure  9-6  shows  the  United  Nations  forecasts  in  greater  detail,  this 
time  on  a  logarithmic  scale  in  which  parallel  lines  indicate  equal  rates  of 
growth,  rather  than  equal  amounts  of  increase. 

All  regions  are  growing  and  will  continue  to  grow,  barring  a  major 
catastrophe.  It  is  natural  that  demographic  evolution  should  have  pro- 
ceeded furthest  in  Western  Europe,  the  birthplace  of  modern  industrial 
civilization.  But  despite  somber  predictions  made  a  decade  ago  no  popu- 
lation decline  in  Europe  is  yet  in  prospect.  In  fact  there  is  some  suggestion 
that  the  very  appearance  of  decline,  as  in  France  before  the  war,  will 
bring  about  reactions  in  public  policy  and  private  attitudes  sufficient  to 
restore  a  moderate  rate  of  growth.  France  today  has  one  of  the  highest 
reproduction  rates  in  Europe. 

Eastern  Europe  is  the  one  major  region  in  which  the  demographic 
losses  of  World  War  II  are  clearly  discernible  in  the  population  curve.  If 
very  recent  information  on  the  rapidity  of  the  birth  rate  decline  in  the 
U.S.S.R.  and  the  satellite  countries  is  accurate  the  United  Nations  fore- 
casts for  this  area  are  too  high. 

In  overseas  Europe— in  the  United  States,  in  Canada,  in  Australasia,  and 
in  temperate  zones  of  South  America— population  growth  is  still  rapid  and 
above  the  world  average.  While  present  growth  rates  may  not  be  main- 
tained, we  may  expect  continued  growth  at  a  less  rapid  pace,  both  from 
immigration  and  from  the  excess  of  births  over  deaths. 

Latin  America  is  the  most  rapidly  growing  major  region.  It  is  now  sur- 
passing America  north  of  the  Rio  Grande  in  population.  Even  with  an 
orderly  demographic  evolution  on  the  pattern  of  Europe,  it  will  have  very 
rapid  increase  over  the  next  generation.  To  the  extent  that  weight  of 
numbers  contributes  to  regional  importance,  Latin  America  will  play  a 
growing  role  in  world  affairs. 

But  the  biological  fate  of  the  species  will  be  decided  in  Asia,  which 
now,  as  throughout  recorded  history,  is  the  principal  home  of  the  human 
race.  Only  catastrophe  will  prevent  an  enormous  growth  of  population  in 
Asia,  a  growth  that  is  gaining  momentum  with  each  new  success  in  public 


326  HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 

health.  This  is  both  necessary  and  desirable.  However,  the  most  rapid 
present  and  potential  growth  often  is  in  areas  least  well  endowed  in  terms 
of  physical  and  cultural  resources  to  meet  the  needs  of  an  expanding 
population. 

The  United  Nations  forecasts  a  population  of  two  billion  in  Asia  in  1980 
or  2.3  billion  if  we  adjust  for  the  new  reports  of  population  growth  in 
China.  We  have  already  mentioned  that  almost  600  million  people  in 
China  are  now  reported  to  be  growing  at  the  rate  of  2  per  cent  or  about 
12  million  persons,  per  year,  the  difference  between  the  reported  birth 
rate  of  37  and  the  reported  death  rate  of  17  per  thousand  population. 

WAR  AND  FUTURE  POPULATIONS 

Finally,  it  must  be  evident  that  the  above  forecasts  ignore  the  possibility 
of  a  major  war.  While  we  may  not  care  to  think  of  war  as  a  "normal" 
phenomenon,  it  certainly  is  a  possibility  within  the  time  span  covered  by 
these  projections. 

The  demographic  impact  of  modern  war  has  been  greatly  exaggerated 
in  the  popular  imagination.  While  war  losses  of  the  two  World  Wars 
seriously  reduced  selected  populations,  their  impact  was  temporary  and 
local,  viewing  the  world  as  a  whole.  Their  impact  was  negligible  in  retard- 
ing the  forward  march  of  world  population  growth.  Aside  from  the  single 
case  of  Eastern  Europe  one  would  have  to  look  very  closely  on  the  two 
charts  to  detect  any  effects  of  the  two  World  Wars. 

This  does  not  in  any  way  minimize  the  personal  tragedy  or  horror  of 
war.  It  merely  reflects  the  fact  that  the  social  and  biological  forces  leading 
to  world  population  growth  represent  basic  and  powerful  forces  that  were 
only  very  temporarily  checked  by  the  two  World  Wars. 

Another  war,  fought  with  the  arsenal  of  horrible  new  weapons,  might 
be  far  more  disastrous  to  the  species.  But  only  about  5  per  cent  of  the 
world's  population  lives  in  its  sixty-odd  urban  agglomerations  of  over  one 
million  inhabitants.  The  destruction  of  all  our  major  cities  would  not 
directly  destroy  a  large  part  of  the  human  race.  For  that  matter  four  or 
five  normal  years  of  world  population  growth  would  completely  replace 
the  population  of  the  United  States  and  six  years  that  of  the  Soviet  Union. 
These  remarks  are  not  intended  to  be  comforting— only  to  put  the  prob- 
lem of  human  survival  in  its  proper  perspective. 


POPULATION  GROWTH  AND  PRESSURE  327 

D.    Structure 

The  previous  discussions  have  emphasized  the  importance  of  changing 
numbers.  It  is  obvious  that  numbers  alone  will  not  determine  demographic- 
influences  on  national  power.  Obviously,  populations  differ  in  their  age 
composition,  degree  of  education,  occupations,  and  other  characteristics 
that  will  determine  their  per  capita  effectiveness  in  contributing  to  na- 
tional power. 

Figures  9-7,  8  and  9  present  a  comparison  of  age  structures  in  countries 
representing  different  stages  in  demographic  evolution.  These  charts  are 
called  "age  pyramids"  because  of  their  characteristic  shape. 

The  age  pyramids  of  any  country  reflect  all  the  things  that  have  hap- 
pened to  its  population  for  the  past  eighty  years  or  more.  The  broadly 
based  youthful  population  of  India  reflects  both  its  high  birth  rate  and  its 
high  death  rate.  Many  children  are  born,  but  in  the  past,  at  least,  these 
were  rapidly  decimated.  Few  survived  to  the  upper  age  groups. 

The  age  pyramid  of  the  Soviet  Union  would  reflect,  in  addition  to  birth 
and  death  rates,  the  drastic  effects  of  war.  The  scars  of  war  are  obvious 
both  in  the  deficits  of  men  among  survivors  of  military  age  at  the  time  of 
conflict,  and  even  more  poignantly  in  the  small  numbers  of  the  age 
groups  born  during  war  and  revolution.  But  the  high  Russian  birth  rate 
has  in  the  past  quickly  repaired  such  losses. 

This  is  not  happening  in  the  United  Kingdom  and  other  Western  Euro- 
pean countries,  however,  where  each  succeeding  group  reaching  age  15, 
20,  and  so  on,  is  smaller  than  the  one  that  preceded  it.  In  other  words,  the 
reservoir  from  which  Western  countries  draw  military  manpower  is  reced- 
ing, whereas  in  the  Soviet  Union,  despite  estimated  direct  war  losses  of 
fourteen  million  persons,  there  is  a  growing  force  of  young  military  man- 
power. 

In  the  West  the  situation  will  be  changed  when  the  children  of  the 
postwar  baby  boom  reach  military  age.  Furthermore  the  large  drop  in  the 
birth  rate  that  apparently  has  occurred  in  the  Soviet  Union  will  begin  to 
be  felt  about  the  same  time. 

Consequently,  present  trends  in  military  manpower  heavily  favor  the 
Soviet  Union  in  relation  to  the  West.  Trends  ten  to  fifteen  years  hence 
may  not. 

A  comparison  of  the  composition  of  the  population  of  several  important 
countries  is  presented  in  Table  9-3.  It  may  be  noted  that  there  is  only  a 


M£ 

INDIA  -  1931 

80* 

|| 

75-80 

1 

70-75 

15-70 

i 

MALE 

SBJI §JB 

FEMA 

to- OS 

55-60 

50-55 

45-50 

40-45 

35-40 

30-35 

25-30 

'> 

20-25 

15-20 

10-15 

' 

5-10 

0-5. 

1 

1 

i         ! 

»         4 

i       : 

1         2 

1       i 

1! 

0          1 

i 

! 

1        * 

1         ! 

i        ( 

1 

'        8 

il 

PERCENT 


).«. 


Fig.  9-7.  India:  Composition  of  Population. 


AGE 

JAPAN    - 

1940 

80  + 

m  ill 

75-80 

70-75 

65-70 

M  A   L    E 

F 

E  M  A  L  E 

60-65 

55-60 

; 

50-55 

45-50 

40-45 

• 

35-40 

30-35 

25-30 

20-25 

15-20 

10-15 

5-10 

■il- 

— 

ii 

4         3         2         1  0  12         3  4         5         6  7         I 

PERCENT 

Fig.  9-8.  Japan:  Composition  of  Population. 


328 


POPULATION  GROWTH  AND  PRESSURE 


329 


AGE 

UNITED 

K 

1  N  G  DOM 

- 

1  948 

80* 

75-80 

70-75 

65-70 

i_ . 

MALE 

w . 

FEMALE 

60-65 

55-60 

50-55 

45-50 

40-45 

35-40 

30-35 

1 

25-30 

20-25 

i 

15-20 

10-15 

5- 

0-5 

m 

1 

8         1 

( 

! 

i 

: 

; 

■ 

ii 
0 

i      : 

i        i 

i        i 

i 

5 

!          8 

PERCENT 


idf 


Fig.  9-9.  United  Kingdom:  Composition  of  Population. 


general  correlation  between  the  relative  size  of  total  populations  and  the 
size  of  the  groups  most  important  to  military  strength. 

Because  of  their  low  birth  rates  during  the  depression  years  the  United 
States  and  Western  Europe  have  relatively  small  contingents  of  males  in 
the  most  crucial  military  age  groups  at  the  present  time.  Thus  while  the 
total  population  of  the  Soviet  Union  is  not  very  much  greater  than  the 
combined  total  population  of  the  four  chief  Western  European  powers, 
the  number  of  males  15  to  24  in  the  Soviet  Union  is  5  million  larger. 
While  the  Soviet  population  is  only  about  20  per  cent  larger  than  that 
of  the  United  States,  it  has  far  more  men  at  the  young  military  ages. 

On  the  other  hand,  the  labor  force  in  the  Western  countries  is  roughly 
proportionate  to  the  total  population.  The  West  is  therefore  better  off  in 
terms  of  industrial  manpower  than  it  is  in  terms  of  prime  military  man- 
power. Furthermore  its  labor  force  is  utilized  primarily  in  non  agricultural 
occupations.  Despite  very  rapid  industrialization,  the  Soviet  population  is 
still  almost  half  agricultural.  In  the  modern  world,  agricultural  population 
contributes  very  little  to  the  industrial  potential  of  the  country.  It  has 
value  as  a  source  of  military  manpower  but  this  in  turn  is  limited  by  the 
capacity  of  the  economy  to  equip  and  support  soldiers  in  the  field.  Defen- 
sively, of  course,  a  large  agricultural  population  may  be  difficult  to  con- 


330  HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 

quer  and  administer.  This  latter  function  has  proved  a  decisive  one  on 
some  occasions,  as  Russia  has  proven  in  its  resistance  to  both  the  Napole- 
onic and  Hitler  invasions  and  as  China  has  demonstrated  in  its  resistance 
to  Japan. 

Another  aspect  of  the  labor  force  potential  is  the  labor  reserves  that 
may  be  drawn  upon  in  an  emergency.  There  are  three  types  of  labor  re- 
serves: the  unemployed,  housewives,  and  the  underemployed,  particularly 
in  agriculture.  To  carry  our  comparison  of  Western  Europe  and  the  U.S.S.R. 
further,  it  may  be  said  that  the  Western  coutries  have  greater  reserves  of 
the  first  two  categories  but  far  less  of  the  third.  Despite  great  economic 
activity  there  is  still  some  unemployment  in  Western  Europe,  but  except 
in  Italy  this  is  not  large  in  relation  to  the  total  labor  force  potential. 

The  most  flexible  part  of  the  labor  reserve  is  women.  In  all  countries 
men  in  the  age  group  from  15  to  59  are  almost  all  gainfully  occupied.  On 
the  other  hand  many  women  of  this  age  group  in  all  countries  are  of 
course  occupied  as  homemakers.  In  the  Soviet  Union  there  has  been  great 
pressure  for  all  women  not  actually  caring  for  small  children  to  enter  the 
labor  force.  About  two-thirds  of  Soviet  women  at  ages  15  to  59  are  in  the 
labor  force.  There  is  little  flexibility  left  for  gaining  woman-power  in  the 
labor  force  in  a  national  emergency. 

By  contrast,  Western  countries  have  a  very  substantial  reserve  in  women 
not  now  gainfully  occupied.  The  proportion  in  the  labor  force  is  much 
less;  in  the  United  States  only  30  per  cent  of  women  at  ages  15  to  59  are 
in  the  labor  force.  Obviously  many  more  than  in  Russia  could  be  drawn 
upon  in  an  emergency,  as  they  were  in  the  United  States  during  the  last 
world  war. 

The  third  element  in  labor  reserve— the  underemployed  in  agriculture- 
is  much  greater  in  the  Soviet  Union  than  in  the  West.  In  a  few  Western 
countries  such  as  Italy,  Spain,  and  Portugal,  there  is  a  substantial  reserve 
of  agricultural  underemployment  but  nothing  to  compare  with  the  Soviet 
Union  and  with  Eastern  Europe  generally.  The  East  has  enormous  re- 
serves of  farmers  inefficiently  employed  in  agricultural  work  who  form  a 
continuing  reserve  of  labor  for  future  industrialization  in  these  areas. 

These  illustrative  comparisons  should  not  be  given  too  great  weight  in 
themselves.  A  large  population  size,  a  large  military  manpower,  a  large 
and  highly  skilled  working  force  are  the  conditions  and  not  in  themselves 
the  fact  of  political  power.  To  these  ingredients  must  be  added  organiza- 
tion, morale,  and  motivation  to  make  this  potential  strength  kinetic. 


POPULATION  GROWTH  AND  PRESSURE  331 


TABLE 

9-3 

Manpower  Comparisons,  Selected  Countries,  1956  * 

(Rounded  to 

Millions) 

TOTAL 
POPU- 

POPU- 
LATION 

MALES 

LABOR   FORCE 

NON- 

AGRI- 

LATION 

15-59 

15-24 

TOTAL 

AGRIC. 

CULTURAI- 

United  States 

168 

96 

11 

70 

64 

7 

Western  European  Powers 

195 

120 

14 

89 

67 

21 

United  Kingdom 

51 

31 

3 

23 

22 

1 

France 

44 

26 

3 

21 

15 

6 

Italy 

49 

31 

4 

22 

13 

9 

Western  Germany 

51 

32 

4 

23 

18 

5 

U.S.S.R. 

200 

127 

19 

86 

49 

37 

*  Data  for  the  United  States  and  the  Western  European  powers  compiled  and  adapted  from  census  and 
official  estimates  of  the  countries  concerned.  Figures  for  the  U.S.S.R.  were  derived  from  official  Soviet  data 
by  the  U.  S.  Bureau  of  the  Census,  Office  of  Foreign  Manpower  Research.  The  labor  force  figures  for  the 
U.S.S.R.  apparently  exclude  several  millions  in  the  armed  services,  in  labor  camps,  in  domestic  service,  in 
the  party  apparatus,  and  in  certain  other  categories  that  would  be  included  in  Western  countries. 


E.    Pressure 

THE  GROWING  POPULATION  IN  A  SHRINKING  WORLD 

In  previous  chapters  it  has  been  noted  that,  geographically  speaking, 
we  live  in  a  shrinking  world.  Modern  transport  and  communication  are 
cutting  down  the  real  distance,  measured  in  travel  time  and  cost,  between 
the  several  parts  of  the  globe. 

Demographically  speaking,  the  opposite  is  the  case:  we  live  in  a  rapidly 
expanding  world.  One  of  the  most  distinctive  features  of  our  age  is  this 
rapid  multiplication  of  our  species  in  all  parts  of  the  world. 

At  the  same  time  hope  is  being  held  out  that  the  human  race  as 
a  whole,  not  just  a  single  class  or  master  race,  can  be  freed  from  the  degra- 
dation of  grinding  poverty  and  needless  suffering.  This  hope  is  justified 
by  technical  achievements  and  by  the  rising  capacity  to  produce.  Prob- 
ably the  cornucopia-minded  are  correct  in  asserting  that  the  world  could 
meet  these  expectations  for  its  present  numbers.  But  a  large  part  of  the 
economic  gains  must  each  year  be  diverted  to  provide  new  places  at  the 
world's  table  rather  than  to  improve  the  fare  of  those  already  here. 

The  "world  population  problem"  turns  out  on  inspection  to  be  a  series 
of  regional  and  national  problems.  Much  more  important  than  the  total 
resources  theoretically  available  in  the  world  are  the  specific  resources 
available  in  relation  to  the  populations  of  specific  countries  and  regions. 
In  fact  even  here  the  oft-discussed  framework  of  the  relation  of  people 
to  resources  offers  a  somewhat  inadequate  statement  of  the  problem. 


332  HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 

Quite  as  important  as  physical  resources  in  relation  to  population  are  the 
crucial  intervening  variables  that  determine  how  effectively  such  re- 
sources are  used  and  converted  to  meet  population  needs.  The  factors  of 
technology,  social  organization,  and  especially  political  stability  are  quite 
as  important  in  determining  levels  of  living  as  the  stock  of  physical  re- 
sources. 

The  greatest  population  pressure,  and  the  greatest  growth  potential,  lie 
in  the  area  sometimes  described  as  Monsoon  Asia,  that  is,  non-Soviet  Asia 
from  Pakistan  east  to  Japan.  Following  is  a  case  study  of  the  problem  of 
people  versus  resources  in  that  crucial  area. 

MONSOON  ASIA 

Half  the  world  lives  in  Monsoon  Asia— the  poorer  half.  By  Western 
standards  the  overwhelming  majority  of  the  population  of  this  region  live 
in  unrelieved  poverty.  If  sheer  poverty  is  a  measure  of  overpopulation,  the 
entire  area  is  desperately  overpopulated.  But  the  relationship  between 
people  and  resources  is  not  a  simple  one. 

Measures  of  Population  Pressure.  Population  pressure  is  not  fully 
measured  by  "man-land  ratios."  These  leave  out  a  vitally  important  middle 
factor— the  effectiveness  with  which  available  resources  are  utilized.  In 
the  broadest  sense  this  is  determined  by  the  cultural  development  of  the 
people— their  motivations,  their  organization,  and  their  skills.  Low  pro- 
ductivity may  reflect  either  population  pressure  or  backward  technology. 
In  Asia  it  undoubtedly  reflects  both.  It  is  difficult  to  isolate  the  impact  of 
limited  resources  and  to  measure  population  pressure  per  se. 

Population  pressure  should  be  felt  most  acutely  in  the  production  of 
absolute  essentials,  and  notably  food.  Figure  9-10  gives  some  measure  of 
the  prewar  relationships  between  people,  land,  and  food  production  in 
Asia  as  compared  with  other  parts  of  the  world.  Asia  was  obviously 
heavily  populated  in  relation  to  arable  land.  In  Eastern  Asia  (China, 
Korea,  and  Japan )  there  was  available  only  half  an  acre  of  cultivated  land 
per  person.  Southern  Asia  was  somewhat  better  off  with  .8  of  a  cultivated 
acre  per  person.  In  these  terms  Southern  Asia  was  in  a  slightly  better 
position  than  Western  Europe  but  was  at  a  serious  disadvantage  in  rela- 
tion to  other  parts  of  the  world,  particularly  North  America. 

The  different  intensity  of  agriculture  leads  to  quite  a  different  compari- 
son in  terms  of  original  calories  per  acre.  Here  Asia  makes  a  much  better 
showing,  albeit  inferior  to  that  of  Western  Europe.  Asia  produces  sub- 
stantially more  per  acre  than  does  the  extensive  agriculture  of  North 


POPULATION  GROWTH  AND  PRESSURE 


333 


PEOPLE,  LAND,  AND  FOOD  PRODUCTION 


North 

Western 

East 

South 

America 

Europe 

Asia 

Asia 

Acres  Cultivated  Per  Person 

total  population 

Llll— IlLlMlll 


farm  population 


0.7 


2.7 


0.5 


• — > 
I 


ml  0.7 


a 


0.8 


i       i 
I        | 


1.2 


Original  Calories  Per  Acre 


2,500 

Original  Calories  Per  Person 
total  population 


7,500 


5,500 

— 

3,600 


JBL10.000 
farm  population 

m  hb  m  m  m 

tl  ri  ::  H  r: 

n   S  m  m  m 


L5.250 


.2,750 


S    Ki    BB  Hi    H  DUB 

giiii     is      s 

iH  JflB.  JfflJH.  JBL5 0,000       JHJH.20,000  J|4,000 


Fig.  9-10.  People,  Land,  and  Food  Production. 


1.2,900 


JH.4,350 
W. 


America  and  the  U.S.S.R.,  but,  in  the  case  of  Southern  Asia,  less  than  half 
as  much  as  Western  Europe. 

The  most  significant  comparison  is  the  output  in  relation  to  the  popula- 
tion, and  especially  to  the  population  in  agriculture.  Despite  intensive 
agriculture,  per  capita  productivity  falls  very  far  short  of  that  in  other 
parts  of  the  world.  This  is  true  even  in  relation  to  Western  Europe,  where 
the  crude  relationships  of  people  to  cultivated  land  might  indicate  as 
acute  a  problem  of  overpopulation  as  in  Asia. 

The  comparative  productivity  of  persons  in  agriculture  is  particularly 


334  HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 

striking.  In  North  America  and  in  Western  Europe  only  20  to  25  per  cent 
of  the  population  is  required  to  produce  the  high  per  capita  food  produc- 
tion indicated  in  Figure  9-10.  In  Asia  it  requires  the  efforts  of  70  per  cent 
of  the  population  to  produce  a  much  lower  food  output.  Output  per  farm 
person  in  the  United  States  is  ten  times  that  in  Asia.  Even  in  Western 
Europe,  per  capita  production  is  five  times  greater  than  in  East  Asia. 

The  data  of  Figure  9-10  suggest  various  quantitative  measurements  of 
"overpopulation."  For  example,  if  the  United  States  ratio  of  people  to 
land  were  taken  as  standard,  80  to  90  per  cent  of  the  Asian  population 
could  be  regarded  as  surplus  (i.e.,  would  have  to  be  eliminated  to  achieve 
a  United  States  relationship  of  people  to  cultivated  land).  By  the  more 
relevant  West  European  standards  of  per  capita  output  of  the  farm  popu- 
lation, up  to  four-fifths  of  the  agricultural  population  in  Asia  could  be 
regarded  as  surplus  and  available  for  nonfarm  employment.  Judged  by 
standards  prevailing  in  other  parts  of  the  world,  even  in  Western  Europe, 
Asia  has  an  enormous  surplus  rural  population  numbering  perhaps  six 
hundred  million.  This  is  a  population  greater  than  that  of  Europe  and  the 
Soviet  Union  combined. 

The  Deterioration  in  Consumption  Levels.  Trends  in  population  and 
production  over  the  past  three  decades  have  tended  to  widen  rather  than 
to  close  these  vast  differentials  in  levels  of  living  between  Asia  and  the 
Western  world.  Thus,  prewar  per  capita  consumption  of  rice  apparently 
declined  in  much  of  Monsoon  Asia  between  the  1920's  and  the  1930s. 
These  declines  are  estimated  to  have  amounted  to  5  per  cent  in  Japan, 
7  per  cent  in  India,  8  per  cent  in  Java,  and  over  10  per  cent  in  the  Philip- 
pines, Korea,  Formosa,  and  Burma.9  They  were  partly  attributable  to  the 
special  depression  conditions  of  the  1930's  and  partly  to  the  substitution 
of  less  favored  grains.  But  in  most  cases  production  did  not  fall;  it  simply 
did  not  keep  pace  with  population  growth. 

Prewar  and  postwar  comparisons  indicate  a  further  deterioration  in  the 
per  capita  consumption  of  food  in  the  majority  of  Asiatic  countries,  again 
attributable  to  population  growth  rather  than  to  production  declines.  By 
contrast,  average  diets  in  North  and  South  America  have  undoubtedly 
improved  and  in  Western  Europe  prewar  levels  are  being  gradually  re- 
gained. 

It  would  almost  certainly  seem  that  Asian  countries  would  be  better  off 
as  regards  food  consumption  if  they  had  substantially  smaller  populations. 

9  V.  D.  Wickizer  and  M.  K.  Bennett,  The  Rice  Economy  of  Monsoon  Asia  (Food 
Research  Institute,  Stanford  University,  1941),  Ch.  10. 


POPULATION  GROWTH  AND  PRESSURE  335 

Even  given  the  existing  backward  agricultural  technology  in  most  parts  of 
Eastern  Asia,  the  populations  would  certainly  be  much  better  fed  if  there 
were,  say,  one  acre  of  cultivated  land  per  person  instead  of  only  half  an 
acre.  Taking  Asian  countries  as  a  whole  and  in  terms  of  existing  technol- 
ogy and  land  utilization,  all  are  certainly  overpopulated— overpopulated 
in  the  sense  that  the  level  of  living  would  be  higher  if  there  were  fewer 
people,  other  conditions  remaining  the  same. 

Possibilities  of  Increased  Production.  Fortunately  we  may  hope  that 
other  conditions  will  not  remain  the  same.  To  say  that  an  area  is  vastly 
overpopulated  is  not  to  say  that  levels  of  living  cannot  be  raised  or  the 
pressure  of  population  ameliorated  through  better  use  of  resources. 

The  history  of  Japan  is  particularly  illuminating  in  this  regard,  since 
Japan  is  one  of  the  most  densely  populated  countries  in  the  world  and  bv 
many  objective  criteria  (for  example,  ratio  of  population  to  arable  land) 
the  most  overpopulated  country.  The  very  rapid  population  growth  occur- 
ring in  Japan  prior  to  the  war  was  not  accompanied  by  deterioration  of 
consumption  levels.  During  the  interwar  period  of  rapid  population 
growth  the  available  food  supply  per  head  of  population  increased  in 
quantity  and  quality  more  than  at  any  other  period  in  Japanese  history.10 
It  is  true  that  Japan  was  importing  rice  from  the  colonies  and  that  special 
circumstances  favored  Japan  in  its  early  period  of  industrialization.  On 
the  other  hand,  Japan  showed  a  rather  remarkable  capacity  to  meet  the 
food  demands  of  its  increased  population  despite  very  limited  natural 
resources. 

Other  Asian  countries  may  not  have  the  great  advantages  earlier  en- 
joyed by  Japan  in  being  able  to  find  a  market  for  industrial  goods  and 
ready  sources  of  food  imports.  On  the  other  hand,  within  all  of  these 
countries  there  are  large  unexploited  areas  which  remain  uncultivated 
owing  to  such  factors  as  lack  of  capital,  ignorance  of  means  of  effective 
utilization,  and  political  instability.  Thus,  in  India  and  China  there  are 
substantial  areas  not  under  the  plow  that  would  be  productive  with 
proper  irrigation.  In  the  three  countries  of  mainland  Southeast  Asia 
(Burma,  Thailand,  and  Indo-China)  the  densely  populated  river  deltas 
are  surrounded  by  large  unexploited  regions,  substantial  portions  of 
which  are  suitable  for  various  types  of  agriculture.  In  Indonesia,  over- 
populated  Java  is  surrounded  by  thinly  settled  outer  islands  that  could 
unquestionably  support  several  times  their  present  inhabitants. 

10  E.  B.  Schumpeter,  et.  al.,  The  Industrialization  of  Japan  and  Manchukuo,  1930- 
1940  (New  York,  1940). 


336  HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 

Furthermore,  a  comparison  of  rice  yields  in  Japan  and  other  Asian 
countries  suggests  the  practical  possibilities  of  better  farm  practices. 
Though  the  soil  of  Japan  is  apparently  not  intrinsically  better  for  rice 
culture  than  in  other  major  producing  areas,  the  yields  are  very  much 
larger.  Japanese  yields  of  35  to  40  bushels  of  cleaned  rice  per  acre  may  be 
compared  with  25  in  China  and  Formosa,  20  in  Korea,  and  about  15  in 
India,  Burma,  Thailand,  and  Java.  Higher  Japanese  yields  are  reported 
to  be  chiefly  attributable  to  the  use  of  better  seeds  and  to  the  effective 
utilization  of  both  industrial  and  organic  fertilizers. 

Or  let  us  assume  that  through  technological  progress  Asia  were  to 
achieve  Western  European  productivity  per  acre.  In  East  Asia  such  an 
achievement  would  increase  production  in  that  area  by  more  than  one- 
third  and  would  feed  two  hundred  million  more  people  at  present  con- 
sumption levels.  In  South  Asia  the  achievement  of  West  European  output 
per  acre  would  double  production. 

Thus,  as  compared  with  the  United  States  and  even  West  Europe,  Asia 
has  a  huge  surplus  farm  population.  But  given  improvements  in  farm 
practices  enabling  the  same  intensity  of  agricultural  production  as  in  West 
Europe  or  Japan,  Asia  could  greatly  increase  her  food  output. 

Recent  Population  Growth.  Population  pressure  in  Monsoon  Asia  is  not 
the  result  of  outstandingly  rapid  growth  in  this  region.  Historically  the 
growth  of  European  populations  has  been  much  more  rapid.  But  while 
the  latter  has  tended  to  decline,  the  population  growth  of  Asia  has  tended 
to  accelerate. 

In  the  recent  past,  rates  of  growth  have  ranged  from  little  or  no  growth 
estimated  for  China  to  2  to  2.5  per  cent  per  year  in  Formosa,  the  Philip- 
pines, and  other  areas  undergoing  especially  effective  public  health  meas- 
ures. More  typical  of  Monsoon  Asia,  however,  is  the  annual  rate  of  growth 
in  prepartition  India  at  1.4  per  cent  between  1931  and  1941.  Between  1937 
and  1947  the  annual  growth  rate  of  Monsoon  Asia  (without  China)  was 
1.2  per  cent.  This  may  be  compared  with  .7  per  cent  during  the  same 
period  in  Western  Europe,  1.1  in  North  America,  about  1.5  per  cent  in 
Africa,  and  about  2  per  cent  in  Latin  America. 

In  Monsoon  Asia  (aside  from  Japan)  the  controlling  factor  in  popula- 
tion growth  has  been  the  death  rate.  The  annual  birth  rate  is  consistently 
high,  ranging  between  35  and  45  per  thousand  in  all  countries.11 

11  As  compared  with  25  in  the  United  States,  16  in  the  United  Kingdom,  22  in  Japan 
(all  1953).  Official  data  for  several  of  the  Asiatic  countries  show  much  lower  rates 
(India  25  in  1952),  but  there  is  ample  evidence  that  these  reflect  failure  to  report  a 


POPULATION  GROWTH  AND  PRESSURE  337 

In  "normal"  years  there  is  an  excess  of  births  over  deaths;  historically 
this  surplus  was  periodically  wiped  out  by  famines,  epidemics,  and  war. 
In  areas  recently  under  European,  American,  or  Japanese  tutelage  these 
periodic  disasters  have  been  progressively  reduced  with  resultant  rapid 
population  growth.  But  even  "normal"  death  rates  in  these  areas  remain 
high  as  compared  to  current  standards  in  the  United  States.  There  is 
present  a  large  "growth  potential"  realizable  through  further  declines  in 
the  death  rate. 

Factors  Affecting  Future  Population  Changes.  The  Potential  Saving  of 
Lives.  As  in  the  West,  declines  in  mortality  in  Asia  preceded  declines  in 
fertility.  Great  improvement  in  most  countries  of  the  region  has  been 
achieved  in  the  control  of  the  acute  and  chronic  contagious  diseases,  and 
great  further  achievements  are  possible  with  comparatively  little  effort. 
The  possibilities  in  this  regard  under  varying  circumstances  are  illus- 
trated by  such  experiences  as  those  in  the  Philippines  and  Formosa, 
where  prewar  achievements  in  reducing  the  death  rate  were  largely  the 
result  of  external  initiative;  in  Japan,  where  great  progress  was  made  at 
native  initiative;  and  in  postwar  Ceylon  and  Japan,  where  startling  reduc- 
tions in  mortality  have  been  accomplished  chiefly  through  the  broadcast 
use  of  the  new  insecticides.12  Where  progress  in  public  health  has  been 
slow  or  negative,  the  explanation  is  to  be  found  in  ineffective  government 
or  political  disturbance  ( as  in  China,  Indonesia,  and  French  Indo-China ) . 


major  proportion  of  the  births.  Following  are  more  reliable  vital  rates  and  comparison 
with  Italian  and  United  States  data: 

Vital  Rates  Per  1000  Population 


COUNTRY 

YEAR 

BrRTH 

DEATH 

NATURAL    INCREASE 

China 

1953 

37 a 

17 a 

20 a 

India 

1931-41 

45  b 

31" 

14  b 

Ceylon 

1953 

39 

11 

28 

Malaya 

1953 

44 

12 

31 

Formosa 

1953 

45 

9 

36 

Japan 

1953 

22 

9 

12 

Italy 

1953 

17 

10 

7 

United  States 

1953 

25 

10 

15 

a  As  reported  from  a  sample  survey  in  Communist  China   (apparently  not  including  areas  affected  by 
floods). 

b  Estimated  from  census  data. 

12  In  Ceylon  the  death  rate  per  thousand  population  was  cut  from  22.0  in  1945 
to  12.6  in  1949  and  10.9  in  1953  (chiefly  through  destruction  of  insect  carriers  with 
DDT).  In  Japan  the  death  rate  has  been  cut  from  prewar  17.0  (1937)  to  11.6  in 
1949,  and  8.9  in  1953,  with  an  annual  saving  of  some  600,000  lives. 


338  HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 

Such  reliable  evidence  as  does  exist  indicates  ( 1 )  that  death  rates  are 
progressively  declining  in  most  of  the  areas,  aside  from  reversals  occa- 
sioned by  war  and  political  disturbances,  and  (2)  that  the  tempo  of 
decline  is  speeding  up.  There  is  no  case  of  general  upward  trend  in  mor- 
tality as  a  result  of  inadequate  nutrition  and  overpopulation,  despite  the 
fact  that  the  per  capita  consumption  in  several  of  the  countries  seems  to 
be  substantially  lower  than  before  the  war.  The  average  food  supply 
seems  to  be  somewhat  lower  but  it  is  better  distributed. 

It  may  be  argued  that  people  are  being  saved  from  disease  only  to  die 
from  famine.  But  this  point  has  demonstratively  not  yet  been  reached  and 
it  seems  probable  that  in  the  near  future  it  will  not  be  reached. 

Theoretically,  increasing  the  death  rate  might  be  an  effective  means  of 
reducing  the  rate  of  population  growth  and  the  pressure  of  population  on 
the  land.  But  only  wars  and  internal  upheavals  may  conceivably  have  this 
effect,  which  would  be  temporary  in  nature. 

Will  the  Birth  Rate  Decline?  So  far  as  may  be  determined  on  the  basis 
of  inadequate  statistical  evidence,  birth  rates  throughout  the  region  are 
high— as  high  or  perhaps  higher  than  those  prevailing  in  Europe  and 
America  a  century  ago.  In  Asia  as  in  other  parts  of  the  world,  high  and 
uncontrolled  fertility  is  an  accompaniment  of  poverty,  ignorance,  and 
subsistence  agriculture.  There  is  no  reason  to  suppose  that  this  high  fer- 
tility represents  a  native  or  racial  characteristic,  or  that  Asians  would  not 
be  responsive  to  the  same  influences  that  brought  about  declines  in  the 
birth  rate  in  Western  countries.  The  difference  is  that,  with  the  single  and 
very  important  exception  of  Japan,  large  Asian  populations  have  not  been 
exposed  to  these  influences.  In  the  twenty  years  preceding  World  War  II, 
the  pattern  of  decline  in  the  Japanese  birth  rate  was  almost  identical  with 
that  experienced  in  Great  Britain  between  1880  and  1900,  when  that 
country  was  at  a  somewhat  comparable  period  of  industrialization  and 
economic  development.  Similar  declines  in  the  birth  rate  have  been  noted 
among  urban  and  middle  class  groups  in  India.  While  conservative  influ- 
ences are  antagonistic  to  regulation  of  births  in  Asia,  up  to  the  present 
time  there  does  not  appear  to  be  any  major  overt  and  doctrinal  religious 
opposition. 

Declining  birth  rates  have  usually  been  regarded  as  exclusively  linked 
with  industrialization  and  urbanization.  If  this  were  true  there  would  be 
little  expectation  of  declining  birth  rates  in  those  large  sections  of  Asia 
where  early  industrialization  does  not  appear  feasible.  However,  an  in- 
spection of  Western  experience  shows  that  the  birth  rate  also  tends  to 


POPULATION  GROWTH  AND  PRESSURE  339 

decline  with  education  and  literacy  even  in  the  absence  of  industrializa- 
tion. In  Europe  declines  in  the  birth  rate  have  been  as  closely  correlated 
with  literacy  as  with  urbanization.13  If  this  also  proves  to  be  true  of  Asia,  it 
is  entirely  possible  that  declines  in  the  birth  rate  may  be  experienced  even 
before  extensive  industrialization. 

The  European  and  Japanese  experience,  and  the  fragmentary  evidence 
for  certain  groups  in  other  Asian  countries,  suggest  that  in  time  the  birth 
rate  will  tend  to  fall  in  Asia  and  that  the  tempo  of  this  decline  will  be 
in  proportion  to  the  rapidity  of  general  economic  and  social  progress  on 
the  Western  pattern.  However,  we  face  the  paradox  that  the  first  effects 
of  modernization  are  to  increase  rather  than  decrease  the  rate  of  growth, 
because  declines  in  the  death  rate  precede  those  in  the  birth  rate.  This 
seems  to  be  a  necessary  transitional  stage.  Controlled  fertility  apparently 
seems  to  be  a  part  of  the  same  complex  of  cultural  factors  that  result  in 
greater  economic  production.  Anything  convincing  people  that  they  can 
control  their  environment  rather  than  accept  it  fatalistically  will  probably 
induce  a  lower  birth  rate. 

Possibilities  for  Emigration.  A  superficially  reasonable  method  of  reliev- 
ing population  pressure  is  emigration.  This  was  one  answer  of  Europe  to 
the  problem  and  resulted  in  the  emigration  of  some  sixty  million  Euro- 
peans overseas.  But,  even  in  the  exceptionally  favorable  situation  prevail- 
ing in  the  nineteenth  and  early  twentieth  centuries  emigration  was  a  real 
solution  of  population  pressure  only  in  certain  smaller  countries  and  re- 
gions, such  as  Ireland,  Scotland,  and  Norway. 

Contemporary  Asia  finds  herself  in  a  very  different  position  from 
Europe  in  the  last  three  centuries.  The  desirable  empty  spaces  of  the  world 
are  already  occupied  or  controlled  by  countries  who  would  resist  the  im- 
migration of  large  numbers  of  Asians. 

Furthermore,  there  are  many  times  as  many  Asians  as  there  were  Euro- 
peans during  the  periods  of  great  overseas  colonization.  Monsoon  Asia  has 
a  natural  increase  at  the  present  time  of  at  least  ten  million  persons  per 
year.  There  are  no  outlets  for  Asiatic  emigration  capable  of  absorbing 
even  a  very  small  fraction  of  this  increase  by  peaceful  means.  Even  if 
other  parts  of  the  world  were  to  absorb  these  huge  numbers,  there  is  no 
assurance  but  that  their  places  would  be  almost  immediately  taken  by 
more  rapid  increase  of  the  population  at  home.  While  a  certain  amount 

13  The  birth  rate  is  low  in  almost  wholly  rural  countries,  such  as  Bulgaria  and  the 
Baltic  countries,  where  literacy  is  relatively  high  (cf.  Dudley  Kirk,  Europe's  Popula- 
tion in  the  Interwar  Years  [League  of  Nations,  1946],  Ch.  IV,  p.  248). 


340  HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 

of  emigration  from  Asia  would  be  desirable  for  various  reasons,  it  will 
have  symbolic  rather  than  actual  value  in  solving  Asia's  problem  of  over- 
population. 

On  the  other  hand,  much  may  be  expected  from  internal  redistribution 
of  population,  especially  in  Southeast  Asia,  where  there  remain  large  areas 
suitable  for  agricultural  exploitation. 

The  Outlook  for  the  Next  Decade.  With  a  modicum  of  peace  we  may 
anticipate  declining  death  rates  in  the  region.  In  all  probability  these  will 
not  be  matched  in  the  earlier  stages  by  declining  birth  rates.  In  the  ab- 
sence of  serious  political  disturbances  the  populations  of  this  region  may 
be  expected  to  increase  1.5  to  2.5  per  cent  per  year,  with  a  general  tend- 
ency for  the  rate  of  growth  to  increase.  Under  optimum  conditions,  eco- 
nomic production  must  be  increased  by  about  2  per  cent  per  year  merely 
to  maintain  the  increasing  population  at  existing  levels. 

The  handicap  of  population  growth  to  economic  progress  may  be  illus- 
trated by  reference  to  India  and  Pakistan.  If  the  population  of  the  Indian 
subcontinent  grows  as  fast  between  1950  and  1960  as  it  did  between  1931 
and  1941  and  between  1941  and  1951  (15  per  cent)  it  will  rise  from  the 
present  425  million  to  about  490  million.  This  would  represent  an  increase 
of  31  per  cent  over  the  prewar  1937  population. 

In  a  carefully  weighed  study  of  the  problem,  Burns  estimates  that  rice 
yields  per  acre  could  be  increased  by  30  per  cent  and  other  crops  cor- 
respondingly.14 But  it  would  require  all  of  this  gain  in  the  next  decade 
merely  to  regain  the  per  capita  consumption  of  the  thirties.  To  regain  the 
production  (and  consumption)  levels  of  the  twenties  would  require  an 
additional  10  per  cent  increase  in  production  in  the  next  decade,  whether 
through  higher  yields  per  acre  or  through  cultivation  of  new  lands.  A  pro- 
duction increase  of  some  40  per  cent  by  1960  is  necessary  merely  to  match 
population  growth  and  recapture  ground  lost  in  the  past  thirty  years.15 

On  the  brighter  side  of  the  picture  is  the  example  of  Japan,  which  illus- 
trates the  possibility  of  doubling  or  even  tripling  food  output  through 
improved  farm  practices.  While  such  goals  are  scarcely  realizable  in  a 
decade,  they  hold  out  the  possibility  that  even  a  rapidly  growing  popula- 
tion can  be  supplied  with  an  improved  diet. 

To  the  extent  that  Asia  is  successful  in  promoting  improved  levels  of 
living,  there  will  initially  be  even  more  rapid  population  growth.  But 

14  Burns,  Technological  Possibilities  of  Agricultural  Development  in  India  (Lahore, 
1944). 

15  These  figures  may  be  pessimistic  owing  to  the  possibility  that  crop  reporting 
in  recent  years  somewhat  underestimates  actual  production. 


POPULATION  GROWTH  AND  PRESSURE  341 

there  is  the  hope  that  such  rising  levels  of  living  will  eventually  be  ac- 
companied by  declining  birth  rates  and  a  smaller  rate  of  growth.  This  is 
the  humane  solution.  No  matter  what  the  rate  of  technological  and  eco- 
nomic progress,  if  the  population  of  Asia  continued  to  grow  at  the  rates 
current  and  likely  for  the  near  future,  population  would  inevitably  over- 
take the  means  of  subsistence  and  would  result  in  a  catastrophe. 


THE  POLITICAL  SIGNIFICANCE  OF  POPULATION  PRESSURE 

The  above  analysis  has  not  been  optimistic.  Even  with  the  most  hopeful 
forecasts  of  economic  development  there  is  no  prospect  whatsoever  that 
the  crowded  populations  of  Asia  can  in  this  generation  match  Western 
levels  of  living.  Yet  this  level  is  dangled  in  front  of  all  underprivileged 
people  as  the  proper  standard  of  material  life.  Understandably  they  desire 
to  achieve  this  standard  and  unwittingly  we  have  encouraged  them  to 
aspire  to  it. 

It  is  also  only  human  nature  that  both  leaders  and  citizens  of  the  under- 
developed areas  will  attribute  their  difficulties  in  attaining  the  Western 
standard  of  living  not  to  their  own  defects  but  to  the  fact  that  they  have 
been  deprived  access  to  the  territories  and  natural  resources  which  West- 
ern people  have  appropriated  for  their  own.  Regardless  of  either  the  ethics 
or  the  logic  of  the  situation,  it  seems  almost  certain  that  the  human  mass 
of  the  crowded  areas  of  the  world  will  regard  this  deprivation  as  unjust, 
and  hence  valid  grounds  for  militant  claims  for  more  territory.  This  will 
be  given  further  animus  by  the  color  prejudice  to  which  they  have  been 
subjected  during  their  colonial  periods. 

It  seems  a  safe  prognostication  that  population  pressure  both  real  and 
imagined  will  be  a  vital  factor  in  the  relations  between  the  new  Asian 
countries  and  the  West. 

At  the  same  time,  population  growth  in  these  countries  consumes  eco- 
nomic product  that  otherwise  could  be  directed  to  better  economic  devel- 
opment. In  a  world  where  an  average  annual  gain  of  3  per  cent  in  the 
national  product  is  regarded  as  very  large,  the  handicap  of  providing  for 
an  annual  growth  of  up  to  2  per  cent  or  more  in  the  population  may  mean 
the  difference  between  success  and  failure— the  difference  between  suc- 
cess and  failure  not  only  in  the  effort  to  raise  levels  of  living  but  even 
more  significantly  in  the  development  of  political  democracy. 

In  this  sense  population  pressure  is  one  of  the  fundamental  forces  mili- 
tating against  the  free  world  in  favor  of  totalitarianism. 


CHAPTER 


10 


Migrations 


MIGRATION  AND  HISTORY 

Man's  history  has  been  described,  with  only  slight  exaggeration,  as  "the 
study  of  his  wanderings."  Some  epochs  of  the  remote  past  are  called 
"periods  of  great  migrations."  This  terminology  presumes  that  at  other 
times  migratory  movements  were  at  a  standstill,  especially  in  the  case  of 
the  so-called  "sedentary"  people.  In  fact,  no  population  is  ever  at  rest. 
Every  epoch  is  a  period  of  "great  migrations."  1 

The  French  geographer  Vidal  de  la  Blache  describes  China  as  the  scene 
of  many  obscure  migrations,  which  taken  together  have  changed  the  face 
of  the  land  and  the  history  of  the  world.  It  is  no  mere  chance  that  the 
books  containing  the  oldest  memories  of  the  human  race,  the  Bible,  the 
ancient  Chinese  scrolls,  and  Mexican  chronicles,  are  full  of  accounts  of 
migrations.  There  is  no  people  without  a  legend  of  a  state  of  unrest, 
of  Trieb,  to  use  Karl  Ritter's  expression,  which  compelled  them  to  move 
from  place  to  place  until  they  found  a  final  resting  place  "constantly 
promised  by  the  divine  voice,  constantly  held  at  a  distance  by  enchant- 
ment." 2  But  often  what  appears  to  be  the  "final  resting  place"  in  the 
longer  span  of  history  proves  to  be  only  a  temporary  refuge. 

There  are  age-old  paths  of  migration  in  natural  highways  provided  by 
the  physical  features  of  the  earth.  Halford  Mackinder  in  his  Democratic 

1  E.  M.  Kulischer,  Europe  on  the  Move:  War  and  European  Population  Changes, 
1917-1947  (New  York,  1948),  p.  8. 

2  P.  W.  J.  Vidal  de  la  Blache,  Principes  de  geographie  humaine  (Paris,  1922), 
p.  70. 

342 


MIGRATIONS  343 

Ideals  and  Reality  has  vividly  described  how,  from  the  fifth  to  the  six- 
teenth century,  wave  after  wave  of  what  he  termed  "brigands  on  horse- 
back" swept  through  the  steppes,  through  the  gateway  between  the  Ural 
Mountains  and  the  Caspian  Sea,  dealing  their  formidable  blows  north- 
ward, westward,  and  southward  against  the  settled  peoples  of  Europe.3 

The  new  means  of  ocean  transportation  evolved  in  Europe  opened  a 
phase  of  the  history  of  migration  which  reached  its  climax  in  the  early 
part  of  this  century.  The  study  of  the  great  transoceanic  migrations  and 
of  their  impact  on  the  lands  beyond  hitherto  unexplored  ocean  spaces 
provides  the  raw  material  of  the  geography  of  colonization  and  overseas 
empires. 

More  recently  the  conquest  of  the  air  and  the  great  improvements  in 
land  transport  have  opened  new  avenues  and  means  of  migration.  The 
natural  barriers  which  formerly  channeled  migration  are  being  increas- 
ingly replaced  by  political  and  other  man-made  barriers  restricting  and 
directing  the  movement  of  people. 

ARE  THERE  PRINCIPLES  OR  "LAWS"  OF 
MODERN  MIGRATIONS? 

In  the  perspective  of  centuries  we  see  the  great  migrations  of  the  past 
as  part  of  vast  historical  processes,  whether  it  be  the  decline  and  fall  of 
Rome  before  the  barbarian  invaders,  the  Aryan  invasions  of  India,  or  the 
European  colonization  of  the  New  World.  It  is  more  difficult  to  perceive 
a  pattern  and  direction  behind  migrations  of  the  present  epoch.  These 
often  seem  aimless  and  nihilistic,  in  themselves  a  denial  of  order  and 
reason.  Sometimes  they  seem  to  reflect  only  the  hatreds  of  those  who 
chance  to  have  the  power  to  wreak  their  vengeance  and  havoc  on  the 
vanquished.  Sometimes  it  is  difficult  to  see  meaning  in  so  much  manifest 
inhumanity.  Yet  our  task  in  political  geography  is  to  divest  ourselves  ( for 
this  purpose)  of  moral  judgments  and  to  seek  meaning  and  direction  in 
the  mass  movements  of  humanity  in  their  relation  to  the  power  of  nations. 

Sixty-five  years  ago  when  Ravenstein  presented  his  famous  papers  on 
migration  at  the  Royal  Statistical  Society  of  Great  Britain,4  the  establish- 
ment of  a  universal  law  of  migration  seemed  possible,  even  certain.  Raven- 
stein's  "Laws"  still  hold  good  for  many  purposes  today,  but  they  apply 
only  to  those  movements  occurring  within  the  "rules  of  the  game"  of 

3  H.  W.  Weigert,  Generals  and  Geographers  (New  York,  1942),  pp.  123-125. 

4  E.  G.  Ravenstein,  "The  Laws  of  Migration,"  Journal  of  the  Royal  Statistical  So- 
ciety, 1885,  pp.  167-235;  1889,  pp.  241-305.  Ravenstein  found  fixed  relationships 
between  distance  of  migration  and  the  number,  the  age,  and  the  sex  of  the  migrants. 


344  HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 

Victorian  Europe.  The  mass  migrations  associated  primarily  with  the  two 
World  Wars  were  entirely  outside  his  frame  of  reference. 

But  the  fact  that  there  are  new  forms  of  migration  does  not  mean  there 
is  no  order  and  direction.  The  pattern  of  change  itself  may  be  more  im- 
portant to  political  geography  than  the  orderly  movements  occurring 
within  the  fixed  precepts  of  a  particular  epoch. 

In  the  discussion  that  follows  we  shall  seek  to  find  the  significance  of 
modern  migration  movements  in,  first,  an  analysis  of  the  types  of  migra- 
tion, and  second,  in  an  analysis  of  the  directions  of  the  movement. 

TYPES  OF  MIGRATION 

There  are  many  ways  of  classifying  migrations— according  to  their  de- 
gree of  permanency,  their  intensity  and  volume,  the  human  units  involved, 
their  motives,  the  distance  traveled,  and  the  direction  of  the  movement. 
These  criteria  give  rise  to  contrasts  between  temporary  and  permanent 
migrations;  individual  versus  communal  or  tribal  migrations;  free  versus 
forced  movements;  internal  versus  international  and  overseas  migrations. 

Each  of  these  represents  a  different  way  of  viewing  the  same  phenome- 
non and  each  in  its  own  way  is  relevant  to  problems  of  political  geog- 
raphy. These  dichotomies  also  suggest  the  various  contrasts  between  the 
migratory  movements  characteristic  of  the  nineteenth  and  twentieth  cen- 
turies. 

Thus  the  overseas  migrations  of  the  nineteenth  and  early  twentieth 
centuries  were  composed  of  individuals  and  family  groups,  whereas  the 
population  transfers  of  the  twentieth  century  were  often  composed  of 
entire  communities;  the  earlier  migrations  gave  effect  to  the  free  and 
voluntary  choice  of  individuals,  whereas  the  war-induced  transfers  were 
motivated  by  fear  and  force;  overseas  migration  involved  continuing  con- 
tacts and  exchanges  between  the  homeland  and  the  migrants,  whereas 
population  transfers  were  intended  to  be  an  absolute  and  irrevocable 
uprooting  from  the  homeland;  finally,  the  population  shifts  connected 
with  the  two  World  Wars  were  chiefly  continental  movements  associated 
with  changed  political  boundaries,  whereas  the  earlier  movements  were 
predominantly  long-distance  migrations  overseas. 

Behind  these  differences  is  a  changed  philosophy  of  the  purposes  and 
rights  involved  in  migration.  The  earlier  philosophy  was  that  the  indi- 
vidual should  be  free  to  choose  his  place  of  residence  in  accordance  with 
the  dictates  of  his  conscience  and  the  welfare  of  himself  and  his  family. 
The  modern  philosophy  is  that  individual  needs  and  desires  must  be 


MIGRATIONS  345 

subordinated  to  the  needs  of  the  community  as  defined  by  the  state.  It 
can  be  said  that  migration  is  controlled  by  conscious  geopolitical  motiva- 
tions. 

It  is  easy  to  conclude  that  the  change  in  type  of  migration  is  a  change 
from  order  to  chaos.  But  the  great  differences  in  the  character  of  the  two 
types  of  migrations  obscure  the  fact  that  both  conform  to  underlying 
forces  of  population  pressure  that  determine  the  direction  and  viability 
of  the  movements. 


POPULATION  PRESSURE  AND  MIGRATION 

Population  pressure  exists  in  two  senses.  There  is  the  absolute  relation- 
ship of  people  to  resources  which  may,  at  a  given  stage  of  the  arts,  mean 
the  difference  between  poverty  and  prosperity.  Until  very  recently  this 
was  the  nature  of  the  problem  in  Monsoon  Asia,  where  there  existed  little 
knowledge  of  better  opportunities  elsewhere  and  even  less  practical  means 
of  taking  advantage  of  these  opportunities.  The  typical  Asian  was  a  peas- 
ant who  knew  little  about  life  beyond  the  confines  of  his  village.  In  such  a 
situation  population  pressure  is  a  latent  but  not  an  active  political  force. 

There  is  the  other  and  relative  sense  of  differential  population  pressure 
between  countries  and  the  changes  in  these  relationships  occurring  over 
time.  To  be  an  active  force  this  pressure  has  reality  only  if  it  is  known  and 
felt  by  the  peoples  concerned.  It  is  the  latter  relative  population  pressure 
that  is  significant  for  problems  of  political  geography. 

Relative  population  pressures  create  tensions  that  are  either  relieved 
through  migrations  or  are  built  up  against  political  barriers  with  the  con- 
stant threat  of  explosion  if  these  barriers  are  weakened.  Some  form  of 
population  pressure  has  been  behind  all  the  great  migrations  in  history. 

Population  pressure  that  gives  rise  to  movement  is  not  just  a  matter  of 
the  mechanical  density  of  the  population.  Often  the  great  migration  pres- 
sures are  from  areas  of  lesser  density  to  higher  density  as  was  true  of  the 
barbarian  invasions  of  the  Roman  Empire,  of  the  Manchu  and  Mongol 
invasions  of  China,  and  of  the  Aryan  invasions  of  India.  The  factor  of 
crude  density  of  population  is  relevant  only  as  it  is  expressed  in  terms  of 
economic  opportunity. 

There  have  been  two  great  magnets  of  economic  opportunity  in  modern 
Europe,  which  has  been  the  source  and  theater  of  the  most  significant 
migrations  in  the  last  two  centuries.  The  first  of  these  was  the  attraction 
of  unpeopled  lands  for  land-hungry  peoples.  In  the  broader  sense  there 
was  the  opportunity  for  personal  and  national  exploitation  of  rich  natural 


346  HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 

resources  in  underdeveloped  and  relatively  unoccupied  countries.  The 
second  magnet  was  the  economic  opportunity  offered  by  industrialization 
and  commerce  in  the  cities  and  industrialized  regions  both  in  Europe  itself 
and  in  Europe  overseas. 

These  two  great  forces  in  migration  give  us  a  key  to  the  understanding, 
in  one  framework,  of  both  the  orderly  migrations  of  the  past  and  the 
seemingly  chaotic  migrations  of  the  current  generation.  The  first  magnet, 
that  of  unpeopled  lands,  induced  the  great  outward  thrust  of  peoples 
from  the  older  centers  of  population,  predominantly  from  Western 
Europe  but  also  to  a  lesser  extent  from  China  and  India.  Cutting  across 
and  in  some  respects  directly  opposing  this  centrifugal  thrust  has  been 
the  centripetal  tendency  reflected  particularly  in  vast  rural-urban  migra- 
tions. 

Most  population  movements  in  the  modern  world  fall  into  a  meaning- 
ful pattern  if  they  are  thought  of  in  terms  of  these  two  great  categories 
and  in  terms  of  the  historical  replacement  of  the  first  by  the  second. 

FREE  MIGRATIONS  OF  EUROPEANS 

In  the  analysis  that  follows  we  will  first  study  free  migrations  and  espe- 
cially the  migrations  associated  with  the  expansion  of  Europe  and,  without 
recounting  the  details  of  this  epic  migration,  attempt  to  point  to  its  lasting 
effects  and  to  its  politico-geographical  legacy  in  the  modern  world.  The 
problem  of  "colonialism"  has  its  origin  in  the  nature  of  European  settle- 
ment and  control. 

The  Politico-Geographical  Legacy  of  European  Settlement.  Whether 
colonization  takes  the  form  of  permanent  settlement  or  whether  its  char- 
acteristic is  the  establishment  of  sovereignty  over  territories  providing 
raw  materials  and  markets  (known  to  the  French  as  colonies  d' exploita- 
tion ) ,  or  whether  we  think  of  the  type  of  colonization  consisting  of  settler 
"islands"  in  alien  lands  (as,  for  instance,  those  of  the  Germans,  Italians, 
and  Japanese  in  Brazil,  or  the  Volga-Germans  in  Russia  before  their  de- 
portation), we  will  always  have  to  go  back  to  the  same  common  denomi- 
nator explaining  the  sources,  the  strength,  and  the  goals  of  colonization  in 
a  particular  area.  Where  Europeans  settled  en  masse  we  find  a  history 
entirely  different  from  those  colonies  in  which  the  economy  was  estab- 
lished on  the  extensive  use  of  indigenous  labor.  The  difference  in  terms  of 
the  political  future  of  these  areas  is  decisive  and  profound. 

For  our  purposes  it  is  desirable  to  distinguish  between  the  various 
demographic  manifestations  of  the  expansion  of  Europe: 


MIGRATIONS  347 

Overseas  Areas  of  Predominantly  European  Settlement.  These  coun- 
tries are  as  a  group  the  wealthiest  in  the  world,  including  the  United 
States,  Canada,  Australia,  New  Zealand,  Argentina,  and  Uruguay.  All  have 
in  effect  achieved  their  political  independence  and,  with  Latin  American 
exceptions,  are  among  the  most  stable  politically  in  the  world  today. 

Areas  of  European  Native  Amalgamation.  In  the  greater  part  of  Latin 
America  European  and  native  populations,  in  some  cases  with  African 
infusions,  are  in  the  process  of  merging.  The  divergent  percentage  of 
European  racial  and  cultural  ingredients  has  resulted  in  a  very  uneven 
degree  of  development  which  is  too  often  concealed  by  the  general  rubric 
"Latin  America."  The  political  regimes  are  often  unstable,  but  culturallv 
and  politically  these  areas  of  settlement  are  firmly  allied  to  the  West. 
While  the  amalgamation  of  European  and  natives  is  most  characteristic 
of  Latin  America,  it  also  exists  to  a  certain  extent  in  the  Philippines  and 
in  Portuguese  Africa,  though  in  these  areas  the  European  biological  and 
cultural  element  is  weaker  than  in  most  of  Latin  America. 

Areas  of  European  Settlement  Where  Europeans  Are  a  Ruling  Minority. 
This  type  of  settlement  exists  chiefly  in  Africa.  In  North  Africa  a  million 
and  a  half  French  rule  three  closely  related  Arab  lands  of  18  million 
inhabitants.  In  the  Union  of  South  Africa,  2.5  million  Britains  and  Boers 
(themselves  in  conflict  with  each  other)  5  hold  the  exclusive  reins  of 
government  in  a  country  with  some  11  million  non whites.  An  even 
smaller  and  less  rooted  white  minority  of  fewer  than  200,000  British 
governs  an  indigenous  population  of  some  3.5  million  in  the  British 
dominion  of  Rhodesia.  These  are  the  hard-core  areas  of  colonialism  that 
the  colonial  powers  and  indigenous  white  populations  cannot  relinquish 
without  threatening  the  most  basic  welfare  and  perhaps  even  the  survival 
of  the  resident  whites. 

Areas  Governed  but  Not  Settled  by  Europeans.  This  type  of  European 
colonization  was  chiefly  characteristic  of  Asia  and  tropical  Africa.  In  Asia 
it  is  dead.  The  Second  World  War  greatly  accelerated  the  development  of 
local  nationalisms  and  brought  to  an  earlier  end  an  otherwise  inevitable 
trend  against  continuing  European  control  of  these  areas.  The  vestigial 
remains  of  direct  European  government  of  Asia,  whether  in  the  Portu- 
guese colonies,  in  Indo-China,  or  in  British  Malaya  and  Hong  Kong  are 
under  the  severest  pressure.  The  same  fate  is  clearly  in  store  for  the  Euro- 
pean colonies  in  tropical  Africa.  Already  Negroes  in  West  Africa,  Nigeria, 
and  the  Gold  Coast  are  making  rapid  strides  toward  independence.  In  the 
East  African  highlands  the  Mau  Mau  revolt,  while  unsuccessful  in  itself, 

5  See  p.  391. 


348  HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 

has  foreshadowed  the  end  of  any  prospect  for  permanent  white  control 
of  the  region. 

Linguistic  Islands.6  The  same  drives  that  sent  sixty  million  Europeans 
to  settle  overseas  lands  impelled  the  colonization  of  Eastern  Europe  by 
Western  Europeans,  particularly  Germans.  Rulers  of  Eastern  Europe 
welcomed  these  settlers  because  of  their  industry  and  relative  advance- 
ment. These  newcomers  chose  to  found  their  own  communities  and  to 
maintain  their  own  customs,  language,  and  religion.  Settled  as  units  and 
having  in  their  view  a  superior  culture  and  higher  economic  status,  these 
linguistic  islands  resisted  assimilation.  The  same  phenomenon  occurred 
less  frequently  in  overseas  migration,  as  in  the  German  settlements  of 
Brazil  that  have  maintained  their  language  and  other  German  character- 
istics for  several  generations.  The  Pennsylvania  "Dutch"  of  the  United 
States  are  such  a  linguistic  island  though  now  far  along  toward  total 
absorption.7  Few  of  these  islands  are  likely  to  survive.  The  German 
Sprachinseln  which  formerly  dotted  Eastern  Europe  have  been  annihi- 
lated. The  modern  nationalisms  of  Europe  doom  such  islands  either  to 
oppression  or  to  assimilation. 

Effect  of  Advance  of  Frontiers.  Finally  a  neglected  aspect  of  the  expan- 
sion of  Europe  is  the  effect  of  the  advance  of  the  frontier  within  the  new 
countries  politically  controlled  by  people  of  European  stock.  These  in- 
ternal migrations  have  had  profound  geopolitical  effects  particularly  in 
the  United  States  and  the  Soviet  Union. 

The  history  of  the  United  States  offers  a  continuous  documentation  of 
the  impact  of  new  areas  which,  in  the  overall  picture  of  trie  nation,  have 
won  their  place  in  the  sun  and,  by  achieving  political  maturity,  have  ex- 
erted their  influence  and  that  of  their  newly  settled  people  upon  the 
internal  and  external  affairs  of  the  Union.  The  "political  geography"  of 
Presidential  elections  may  serve  as  illustration:  until  Buchanan's  Presi- 
dency all  Presidents  came  from  the  eastern  seaboard,  except  for  the  Ten- 
nessean  Jackson.  From  Lincoln  to  McKinley,  the  majority  came  from  the 
Middle  West  but  east  of  the  Mississippi.  Since  Theodore  Roosevelt,  we 
find  a  greater  geographical  variety,  but  also  the  first  Presidents  from  west 
of  the  Mississippi  ( Hoover,  Truman,  and  Eisenhower ) . 

6  See  the  detailed  discussion  of  linguistic  factors  in  political  geography  in  Chapter 
11,  pp.  383-403. 

7  An  interesting  example  of  such  an  island  is  that  of  the  Russian  sect  of  the  Sons 
of  Freedom,  the  Dukhobors,  whose  members  left  Russia  at  the  beginning  of  the 
century  in  search  of  religious  and  political  freedom  and  who,  as  squatters  in  British 
Columbia,  engaged  in  a  last-stand  struggle  against  the  Canadian  government,  re- 
sisting assimilation  in  the  Canadian  community. 


MIGRATIONS  349 

Thus  the  history  of  internal  migration  in  the  United  States  offers  an 
excellent  illustration  of  the  important  principle  that  if  the  factors  of  in- 
stability and  change  motivated  by  internal  migration  are  of  major  pro- 
portions they  will  redistribute  power  within  a  nation.  A  classical  example 
is  the  decisive  break  which  began  in  the  United  States  in  the  1850's,  when 
a  large-scale  colonization  of  the  Great  Plains  redrew  the  population  distri- 
bution map  of  the  country.  Hitherto  this  had  shown  the  European  settle- 
ments clinging  to  the  Atlantic  coast,  their  penetration  inland  normally 
limited  to  a  strip  within  a  hundred  miles  of  tidewater.  The  map  of  the 
population  "centers"  in  the  United  States  with  the  period  between  1790 
and  1950  8  is  a  graphic  illustration  of  the  "Westward  Course  of  Empire" 
trend  which,  with  different  connotations,  is  still  underway.  Since  1790,  the 
center  of  population  in  the  United  States  has  not  deviated  more  than  a  few 
miles  from  its  original  latitude,  close  to  39°  N,  but  it  has  moved  steadily 
westward.  In  a  century  and  a  half  the  center  of  population  has  moved 
about  six  hundred  miles,  at  an  average  speed  of  four  miles  a  year.  The 
shift  was  particularly  rapid  (more  than  five  miles  a  year)  between  1830 
and  1890.  It  then  slowed  down,  especially  after  1910,  but  quickened  dur- 
ing World  War  II.  The  growth  of  California,  which  has  continued  after 
1945,  was  and  still  is  instrumental  in  drawing  the  country's  center  of 
population  further  westward. 

The  student  of  politics,  both  on  the  national  and  state  level,  will  dis- 
cover important  changes  in  the  composition  of  population  groups  as  the 
result  of  these  shifts. 

The  American  example  repeats  itself  in  all  national  territories  endowed 
with  large  space.  The  westward  course  of  internal  migration  in  the  United 
States  is  paralleled  by  the  many  waves  of  migration  southward,  north- 
ward, and  eastward  which  shaped  the  history  of  Russia  and  of  the 
U.S.S.R.  The  internal  geography  of  the  Soviet  Union  cannot  be  under- 
stood without  constant  reference  to  the  mass  migrations  and  population 
transfers  which  took  place  during  its  entire  turbulent  history,  starting  with 
the  forced  resettlements  of  the  collectivization  period  during  1929  and 
1930  and  assuming  momentum  again  in  1932  and  1933  when  mass  famines 
starved  out  many  villages  and  drove  millions  to  the  cities.  As  a  result  of 
planned  population  transfers  between  1927  and  1939,  the  Urals,  Siberia 
and  the  Far  East,  as  well  as  Central  Asia  (in  particular  Kazakhstan), 
became  the  receiving  centers  of  new  waves  of  migration  involving  about 
five  million  people.9  Since  the  war,  migrations  continue  as,  for  instance, 

8  See  Fig.  18-1,  p.  572. 

9  For  a  detailed  discussion  see  Kulischer,  Europe  on  the  Move,  pp.  79-112. 


350  HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 

to  the  labor  camps  scattered  in  inhospitable  regions  over  the  Soviet 
Union,10  and  most  important,  the  mass  movements  from  the  villages  to 
the  towns  and  cities.  This  farm-to-town  migration  is  rapidly  turning  the 
Soviet  Union  into  an  urbanized  nation. 

THE  MIGRATION  CYCLE  IN  EUROPE 

Historically,  mass  migration  from  Europe  has  been  associated  with  a 
particular  stage  of  economic,  social,  and  political  development.  It  has  not 
been  a  purely  rational  movement  from  the  areas  of  lowest  income  or 
greatest  physical  poverty.  People  in  such  areas  usually  lack  knowledge, 
means,  and  abilities  for  taking  advantage  of  opportunities  overseas.  It  has 
rather  been  a  function  of  a  particular  stage  in  the  transition  from  an  essen- 
tially self-sufficient  peasant  economy  to  a  modern  industrial  and  urban 
economy.  The  sources  of  mass  overseas  migration  were  first  in  the  British 
Isles  in  connection  with  early  industrialization  and  the  related  agricultural 
enclosure  movement.  The  latter  dispossessed  the  English  yeoman  and  the 
Scottish  crofter  and  gave  them  impetus  to  seek  land  and  fortune  overseas. 
They  were  soon  joined  by  the  Irish  cottager  who  suffered  acute  pressure 
of  population  on  the  land. 

The  emigration  "fever,"  as  it  has  sometimes  been  described,  moved  in 
ever-widening  concentric  rings  as  modern  influences  spread  from  their 
centers  of  origin  in  England,  the  Low  Countries,  and  later  Western  Ger- 
many. The  "fever"  was  associated  with  a  particular  stage  in  the  transition 
when  the  horizons  of  life  in  the  rural  areas  began  to  rise  beyond  the 
boundaries  of  the  village  to  the  world  at  large.  New  aspirations  were 
aroused  by  improved  communication,  transportation,  by  free  public  edu- 
cation, and  by  the  invasion  of  the  money  economy. 

In  its  demographic  aspects,  this  is  also  a  period  of  transition  in  which 
improvements  in  nutrition,  and  especially  simple  public  health  precau- 
tions, were  bringing  down  the  death  rate  without  comparable  declines  in 
the  birth  rate.  The  result  was  a  rapid  increase  in  population.  In  the  rela- 
tively static  agrarian  economy  of  these  areas  this  situation  provided  the 
push  to  make  new  vistas  beyond  the  village  boundaries  even  more  attrac- 
tive. 

The  way  in  which  the  migration  fever  spread  in  concentric  circles 
across  Europe,  especially  from  west  to  east  and  from  north  to  south,  river 
by  river,  province  by  province,  is  admirably  documented  by  Marcus  Lee 
Hansen  in  his  classic  studies  of  nineteenth  century  migration  to  America.11 

10  Ibid.,  p.  93. 

11  M.  L.  Hansen,  The  Atlantic  Migration  (Cambridge,  Mass.,  1951). 


MIGRATIONS  351 

Already  by  1800  economic  opportunities  as  reported  in  letters  by  family 
and  friends  overseas  were  the  chief  motive  for  migration. 

As  economic  development  progressed,  opportunities  for  employment 
became  increasingly  available  in  nearby  factory  towns  and  commercial 
centers.  These  offered  an  alternative  to  overseas  migration.  Such  "inter- 
vening" opportunities  characteristically  resulted  in  a  reduction  in  the  rate 
of  international  migration  which,  for  example,  was  already  evident  in 
England  and  Wales  as  early  as  1860  and  in  Germany  and  Scandinavia  in 
the  1880's  and  1890's. 

As  is  widely  known,  the  great  sources  of  overseas  migration  in  the  earlv 
twentieth  century  had  already  moved  across  Europe  to  the  less  developed 
rural  areas  of  Poland,  Austria-Hungary,  and  southern  Italy.  This  great 
historic  process  was  drastically  inhibited  by  the  first  World  War,  bv 
immigration  restrictions  in  the  overseas  countries,  and  by  the  Russian 
Revolution.  Indeed,  it  is  a  likely  but  unproved  hypothesis  that  the  block- 
age of  movement  from  the  east  and  the  lack  of  ready  outlets  for  popula- 
tions from  Eastern  Europe  may  be  related  to  the  violence  with  which  the 
East  in  the  course  of  the  past  generation  has  thrown  off  the  former  eco- 
nomic, cultural,  and  political  leadership  of  the  West. 

DIRECTIONS  OF  MIGRATORY  PRESSURE  IN  EUROPE 

By  meaningful  yardsticks  population  pressure  in  Europe  during  the  past 
two  or  three  generations  has  been  greatest  in  Eastern  and  Southern 
Europe,  much  less  in  Northwest  Europe.12  This  differential  pressure  has 
been  reflected  (a)  in  the  predominance  of  peoples  from  these  areas  in 
overseas  migration,  (b)  in  the  migrations  from  the  peripheral,  predomi- 
nantly agricultural  regions  to  the  industrial  cores  of  Western  Europe 

12  Measures  of  population  pressure  relevant  to  Eastern  Europe  include,  inter  alia, 
(a)  density  of  farm  population  on  arable  land,  (b)  agricultural  underemployment  as 
measured  by  low  outputs  per  unit  of  labor,  (c)  ratios  of  entrants  into  the  working 
ages  (or  the  labor  force)  to  departures  from  these  ages  through  death  and  the 
attainment  of  retirement  age.  All  of  these  applied  to  Eastern  European  countries 
reveal  heavy  population  pressure  before  World  War  II. 

In  a  very  fully  documented  study  relating  to  the  interwar  period,  estimates  were 
made  of  "surplus"  agricultural  populations  (i.e.,  agricultural  underemployment)  in 
Eastern  and  Southern  European  countries,  assuming  existing  (1931-35)  production 
and  the  European  average  per  capita  level  of  production  for  the  farm  population.  The 
estimates  of  surplus  population  so  derived  ranged  from  zero  (the  European  average) 
in  Czechoslovakia  to  50  per  cent  or  more  of  all  the  farm  populations  in  Greece,  Poland, 
Rumania,  Bulgaria,  and  Yugoslavia.  The  "surplus"  agricultural  population  amounted 
to  4.9  million  (27  per  cent)  in  Italy;  1.4  million  (12  per  cent)  in  Spain;  and  1.4 
million  (47  per  cent)  in  Portugal.  Cf.  W.  E.  Moore,  Economic  Demography  of 
Eastern  and  Southern  Europe  (Geneva,  1945),  Table  6,  pp.  63-64. 


352  HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 

in  England,  Northern  France,  Western  Germany,  and  the  Low  Countries. 

In  the  last  full  decade  of  "free"  migration  from  1901  to  1910  Eastern  and 
Southern  European  countries  contributed  77  per  cent  of  the  overseas  mi- 
gration from  Europe  as  compared  with  23  per  cent  of  "old"  emigration 
from  Northwest  Europe.13  Fifty  years  earlier,  in  the  decade  1851  to  1860, 
less  than  five  per  cent  of  European  emigrants  were  from  the  areas  of 
"new"  migration  and  over  95  per  cent  were  from  Northwest  Europe. 

Paralleling  this  change  in  the  composition  of  overseas  migration,  there 
was  within  Europe  a  growing  migration  from  the  rural  hinterlands  to  the 
industrial  regions  of  Europe.  There  was  the  flight  of  German  agricul- 
tural workers  in  the  East  to  the  cities  and  to  the  Ruhr.  Their  places  were 
taken  by  Polish  seasonal  workers  who  came  across  the  boundary  for  the 
harvests.  Already  before  World  War  II  large  numbers  of  Italians,  Span- 
iards, and  Eastern  Europeans  were  moving  into  France,  and  in  the  inter- 
war  period  France  replaced  the  United  States  as  the  leading  destination 
of  European  migrants.  This  period  saw  the  influx  of  Eastern  Jews  into 
Germany  and  this,  however  unjustifiably,  contributed  to  the  later  violent 
Nazi  oppression  of  the  Jewish  peoples. 

Since  about  1890  the  prolific  Eastern  European  peasant  (usually  a 
Slav)  has  been  exerting  economic  and  demographic  pressure  against  the 
more  urban,  less  reproductive  Central  European  (usually  a  German), 
even  in  the  face  of  political  domination  by  the  latter.  In  this  he  was  al- 
ready reversing  the  earlier  true  Drang  nach  Osten  of  the  German  peoples 
that  drove  back  the  Slav  from  the  Elbe  to  the  Niemen  and  established 
German-speaking  colonies  all  the  way  across  Europe  to  the  Volga  River. 
Already  before  World  War  I  the  efforts  of  Central  European  nations  to 
strengthen  their  Eastern  marches  with  Central  European  settlers  were 
failures  because  this  effort  attempted  to  stem  and  reverse  the  tide  of  basic 
demographic  and  socio-economic  trends.  The  displacement  of  the  earlier 
ruling  elements  in  the  interwar  years  was  successful  because  it  accorded 
with  the  fundamental  demographic  pressures. 

The  demographic  pressures  in  Eastern  Europe  were  partially  reflected 
in  successful  revolts  from  Western  domination  after  World  War  I— revolts 
legitimized  in  the  principle  of  self-determination  and  the  establishment  of 
the  secession  states.  Then  World  War  II  broke  down  all  barriers  and  re- 
leased a  tremendous  westward  thrust  of  the  Slav.  The  displacement  of 

13  The  regions  of  "old"  emigration  include  the  British  Isles,  Germany,  Scandinavia, 
France,  the  Low  Countries,  and  Switzerland.  The  region  of  "new"  emigration  includes 
the  remainder  of  Europe. 


MIGRATIONS  353 

German  by  Slav  has  been  successful  because  it  swam  with  the  underlying 
demographic  pressures,  just  as  the  failures  of  the  German  in  displacing 
the  Pole  were  due  to  the  fact  that  this  effort  attempted  to  stem  and  reverse 
the  tide  of  basic  economic  and  social  trends. 

The  population  pressures  of  Southern  Europe  (Italy,  Spain,  Portugal, 
and  Greece)  have  neither  been  so  acute  nor  so  dramatic  in  results  as 
those  of  the  East.  In  terms  of  European  averages  the  surplus  populations 
were  proportionately  smaller,  the  rates  of  population  growth  historically 
less,  than  in  the  East.  Furthermore,  outlets  for  migration  were  more 
readily  found— for  Italians  in  France,  in  Belgium,  in  Luxembourg,  and  in 
Switzerland;  for  Spaniards  in  France;  and  for  all,  overseas.  Within  Italy, 
southern  Italians  found  opportunities  in  the  industrialized  north  and  simi- 
larly within  Spain  the  industries  of  Catalonia  and  the  Basque  regions  met 
some  of  the  needs  of  the  surplus  population  in  the  south.  Population 
pressure  was  most  acute  in  Greece,  where  the  exchange  of  populations 
following  World  War  I  had  forced  that  small  country  to  absorb  a  mil- 
lion refugees  from  Asia  Minor.  The  chief  locations  of  crowded  settlement 
in  Macedonia  were  also  strong  centers  of  disaffection  following  World 
War  II. 

Nevertheless  the  problem  of  population  pressure  was  ( and  is )  real.  The 
farm  product  per  farm  worker  in  Italy  is  less  than  half  that  in  France,  not 
because  the  Italian  farmer  is  less  skillful  or  less  industrious  but  because, 
on  the  average,  he  has  only  half  as  much  land.14  The  situation  is  com- 
parable in  Portugal,  worse  in  Greece. 

The  differential  population  pressure  is  accentuated  by  the  dynamics  of 
the  labor  force.  In  a  rapidly  growing  population  far  more  persons  enter 
the  labor  market  each  year  than  leave  through  death  and  retirement.  Italy 
must  accommodate  over  300,000  more  persons  in  the  working  ages  each 
year,  while  in  the  United  Kingdom  and  France  the  population  of  working 
age  is  now  almost  stationary.  These  figures  are  certainly  not  unrelated  to 
the  one  and  a  half  million  unemployed  chronically  reported  in  Italy  since 
the  war.  Similarly  Greece  and  Portugal,  each  with  roughly  eight  million 
inhabitants,  have  had  to  absorb  sixty  to  sixty-five  thousand  new  workers 
each  year,  while  Belgium  (eight  million)  and  Sweden  (seven  million) 
have  each  had  annual  increments  of  under  ten  thousand. 

It  should  be  noted  that  population  pressure  in  Italy  is  more  the  result 

14  The  relative  figures  for  about  1930  on  density  of  agricultural  population  per 
square  kilometer  of  "arable-equivalent"  agricultural  land  are  the  following:  France— 
28.8;  Italy-53.4;  Portugal-49.5;  Spain-34.0;  and  Greece-86.7  (Moore,  op.  cit., 
pp.  197-204). 


354  HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 

of  past  than  of  present  growth.  The  current  growth  in  Italy  represents  the 
inertia  of  the  past,  and  it  will  disappear  unless  there  is  a  sharp  reversal  in 
the  present  downward  trend  in  the  birth  rate.  The  same  forces  seem  to  be 
at  work  in  Spain,  and  are  at  an  earlier  stage  in  Portugal  and  Greece. 

THE  URBAN  DRIFT 

In  all  countries  there  has  been  a  universal  movement  to  the  cities  from 
the  countryside.  The  uprooting  involved  in  this  movement  was  enormous 
—some  150  million  or  one-third  of  all  Europeans  were,  in  the  interwar 
period,  living  outside  the  commune  of  their  birth;  over  half  were  outside 
the  province  or  department  of  their  birth.  These  latter  migrants  particu- 
larly were  persons  who  had  moved  to  the  towns  and  cities  from  the  vil- 
lages and  farms. 

Already  by  1880  overseas  migration  was  primarily  a  movement  to  the 
cities  of  the  New  World.  In  the  United  States  for  example  80  per  cent 
of  the  foreign  born  represented  in  the  1940  census  were  living  in  urban 
areas  as  compared  with  only  50  per  cent  of  the  native  white  of  native 
parentage. 

Likewise  the  greater  part  of  the  migration  to  Australia  was  to  the  great 
cities  of  Sydney,  Melbourne,  and  Brisbane;  in  Argentina  the  bulk  of  the 
immigration  was  absorbed  in  Buenos  Aires;  in  Brazil  the  cities  of  Sao 
Paulo  and  Rio  de  Janeiro  were  the  chief  attractions;  in  none  of  these 
countries  did  large  numbers  of  immigrants  go  directly  to  the  farms  or  to 
the  small  towns.  Within  these  overseas  countries  there  was  little  new 
settlement  after  1900.  On  the  other  hand,  within  each  of  these  overseas 
countries  there  was  a  great  tide  of  rural-urban  migration.  Even  the  west- 
ward movements  in  the  United  States  after  1900  were  movements  pri- 
marily from  Middle  Western  farms  and  small  towns  to  the  cities  of  the 
Pacific  Coast. 

Similarly  in  the  Soviet  Union  the  eastward  migrations  into  Asia,  while 
in  one  respect  a  continuation  of  the  expansion  of  the  European  settlement 
area,  were  in  another  respect  a  migration  from  the  farms  of  European 
Russia  to  the  new  industrial  cities  beyond  the  Urals. 

In  Western  civilization  the  attractions  of  the  city  have  come  to  out- 
weigh greatly  those  of  unsettled  lands,  not  only  because  the  best  lands 
in  the  temperate  zone  have  been  occupied  but  also  because  the  driving 
aspirations  are  those  achieved  only  in  city  life. 

The  greatest  attraction  to  international  migrants  exists  where  these  two 
forces  are  more  or  less  combined,  as  in  the  cities  of  the  New  World. 


MIGRATIONS  355 

Thus  the  direction  of  population  pressure  in  the  Western  world  is  from 
the  farm  and  the  small  town  to  the  city  and  especially  to  the  cities  of 
America.  At  least  this  is  the  choice  of  migrants  in  the  absence  of  coercion 
and  political  barriers.  A  second  choice  of  migrants  has  been  the  urban 
and  industrial  centers  of  Western  Europe. 

These  choices  were  freely  open  to  most  of  the  populations  of  northwest 
Europe  because  United  States  quotas  favored  them  and  because  major 
economic  centers  were  within  their  territories.  In  part  this  latter  oppor- 
tunity was  available  to  southern  Europeans  through  migrations  to  neigh- 
boring France,  and  in  any  case  there  were  industrial  regions  in  Italy  and 
Spain  to  absorb  some  of  the  surplus  populations. 

The  problem  was  more  severe  and  the  solutions  less  available  in  Eastern 
than  in  Southern  Europe.  It  was  this  demographic  context  in  which  oc- 
curred the  massive  population  transfers  set  in  motion  by  Nazi  aggression, 
war,  and  postwar  settlements. 


FORCED  MIGRATIONS 

"The  Nation  of  the  Homeless."  In  1952  an  editorial  in  The  New  York 
Times  spoke  of  the  somber  fact  that  "in  this  century  the  homeless  form 
one  of  the  great  nations  of  the  world."  The  displaced  person  is  as  much 
a  symbol  of  this  century  as  is  the  broken  atom. 

The  dispossessed  and  uprooted,  in  the  uninspired  language  of  the 
bureaucracies,  are  classified  as  expellees,  deportees,  refugees,  and  dis- 
placed persons.  In  many  cases  they  remain  unabsorbed  by  the  nations 
within  whose  borders  they  have  found  refuge.  Yet  they  have  changed  the 
structure  of  the  human  and  political  geography  of  the  regions  in  which 
they  have  settled,  just  as  their  flight  or  expulsion  has  changed  the  struc- 
ture of  the  regions  they  have  left. 

The  regions  from  which  large  sections  of  the  population  have  been 
uprooted,  as  well  as  those  where  the  refugees  and  the  expelled  have  come 
to  rest,  stand  out  on  the  political  map  as  danger  zones.  Vacuums  have 
been  created  by  the  expulsion  of  large  minorities.  At  the  same  time  new 
irredentist  agitation  is  created  in  the  receiving  countries.  Many  external 
and  internal  problems  involved  in  the  integration  of  the  newcomers,  or 
more  often  the  failure  to  achieve  such  integration,  confront  both  the  na- 
tion and  the  international  organizations  concerned. 

These  problems  of  our  age  make  it  mandatory  to  the  student  of  political 
geography  to  observe  carefully  the  changes  in  the  ethnic  and  national 


356 


HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 


composition  of  nation  states  which  are  due  to  mass  migrations  and  popu- 
lation transfers.15 

Population  Transfers  in  Europe.  The  political  map  of  Europe  and  of 
the  European  lands  of  the  Soviet  orbit  has  undergone,  since  1939,  more 
basic  changes  stemming  from  mass  population  movements  than  the  con- 
tours of  changed  political  boundaries  would  reveal.  The  gist  of  the  long 
story  of  migrations  initiated  in  Europe  by  World  War  II  is  contained  in 
the  following  chart  prepared  by  E.  M.  Kulischer,  which  lists  movements 
from  1939  to  1947: 

TABLE  10-1  * 
Redistribution  of  Population  Produced  by  World  War  II  a 


YEARS 


ROUTE 


GROUP 


Transfer;  Evacuation;  Flight  of  ethnic  Germans. 


1939-43  Italy  (south  Tyrol)  to  Austria  and  Germany 

1944  Rumania  to  Germany  and  Austria 

1944  Yugoslavia  to  Germany  and  Austria 

1944  Rumania  to  U.S.S.R. 

1944  Yugoslavia  to  U.S.S.R. 

1944-46  Hungary  to  Germany  and  Austria 

1944-45  U.S.S.R.  (Russian  East  Prussia)  to 

Germany 

1944-45  Old  Poland  to  Germany 

1944-47     New  Poland   (former  eastern  Germany)   to 

Germany 
1944-45     New  Poland   (former  eastern  Germany)   to 

Denmark 
1945-46     Czechoslovakia  to  Germany  (partly  to 

Austria ) 
1945-46     Soviet  Zone  to   United   States   and   British 

zones  in  Germany 


80,000  Tyrolese  Germans 
200,000  ethnic  Germans 
250,000  ethnic  Germans 

70,000  ethnic  Germans 
100,000  ethnic  Germans 
200,000  ethnic  Germans 

500,000  Reich  Germans 
1,000,000  ethnic  Germans 
( Polish    citizens    and    trans- 
ferees from  other  countries )  b 

6,000,000  Reich  Germans 

100,000  Reich  Germans  c 

2,700,000  ethnic  Germans 

4,000,000  Reich  Germans 


*  Reproduced  by  permission  of  the  Columbia  University  Press  from  Kulischer,  Europe  on  the  Move. 

a  The  transfer  of  230,000  Germans  from  Austria  to  Germany  is  not  mentioned;  it  was  partly  a  return 
cf  Reich  Germans  who  had  migrated  to  Austria  after  March,  1938,  and  partly  a  transfer  of  Sudeten  German 
refugees  comprised  by  the  total  of  2,700,000.  Ethnic  Germans  transferred  in  1939-44  to  the  Warteland  are 
not  listed  separately.  Apart  from  those  drafted  in  the  German  army,  most  of  them  left  for  Germany. 
Se  note  b.  Volga  Germans  are  listed  under  Population  Movements  within  the  U.S.S.R. 

b  In  1939-44  about  800,000  ethnic  Germans  were  transferred  to  the  Warteland  (partly  to  central 
Poland),  mainly  from  the  Baltic  countries,  eastern  Poland,  Rumania,  and  the  southern  part  of  the  U.S.S.R. 

c  Later  transferred  to  Germany. 

15  The  reader  is  referred  to  the  following  sources  for  a  comprehensive  treatment 
of  population  transfers:  W.  S.  and  E.  S.  Woytinsky's  World  Population  and  Pro- 
duction (New  York,  1953),  pp.  66-110,  is  the  most  comprehensive  short  treatment 
of  the  subject  and  offers  the  gist  of  the  available  statistical  material  on  individual 
regions.  The  standard  works  on  displacements  of  populations  in  Europe  are:  E.  M. 
Kulischer,  The  Displacement  of  Population  in  Europe  (Montreal,  1953),  and  the 
same  author's  Europe  on  the  Move:  War  and  Population  Changes,  1917-1947  (New 
York,  1948),  and  J.  B.  Schechtman,  European  Population  Transfers,  1939-1947  (New 
York,  1946). 


MIGRATIONS 


357 


YEAKS 


ROUTE 


CROUP 


Population  Movements  of  Non-Germans  From,  Into,  and  Within  Poland* 
1939-44       Poland  to  Germany,  Austria,  and  Italy  275,000  Polish  displaced 


1939-47      Poland  through  U.S.S.R.,  the  Balkans,  and 
Western  Europe  to  Great  Britain 


1944-46       U.S.S.R.   (former  eastern  Poland)  to  New 

Poland 
1946  U.S.S.R.  to  Poland 

1944-46       Poland  to  U.S.S.R. 


1946  Various  European  countries  to  Poland 

1945-47       Old  Poland  to  New  Poland 


persons 

160,000  members  of  Polish 
army  ( including 
families ) 

1,000,000  Poles 

50,000  Polish  Jews  f 
518,000  Ukrainians, 
Belorussians  and 
Lithuanians 
60,000  returned  Polish 
emigrants 
3,000,000  Poles 


Population  Movements  of  Non-Germans  From,  Into,  and  Within  Czechoslovakia 


1945-46      U.S.S.R.    ( Carpatho-Ukraine )    to    Czecho- 
slovakia 

1946  U.S.S.R.  (Volynia)  to  Czechoslovakia 

1946-47       Rumania  to  Czechoslovakia 

1946-47       Western   and   central   Europe   to    Czecho- 
slovakia 

1946-47       Hungary  to  Czechoslovakia 
1946-47       Czechoslovakia  to  Hungary 
1946-47       Inner  Czechoslovakia  to  the  border  region 
( Sudetenland ) 

1946-47       Slovakia  to  Bohemia  and  Moravia 


30,000  Czechs  and 

Ukrainians  e 
33,000  ethnic  Czechs 
30,000  ethnic  Czechs  and 

Slovaks 

30,000  returned  Czecho- 
slovak emigrants 
100,000  ethnic  Slovaks  " 
100,000  Magyars 

1,800,000  Czechs  and 
Slovaks 
180,000  Slovaks  and 
Magyars 


Population  Movements  of  Non-Germans  From  and  Into  Yugoslavia 


1941-47       Yugoslavia  to  Germany,  Austria,  and  Italy 

1946-47       Yugoslavia    (Istria,    Fiume,    and  Zara)    to 

Italy 
1946-47       Yugoslavia  to  Hungary 
1946-47       Hungary  to  Yugoslavia 


90,000  Yugoslav  displaced 
persons  and  refugees 

140,000  Italians 
40,000  Magyars  h 
40,000  Serbs,  Croats,  and 
Slovenes  h 


Population  Movements  of  Non-Germans  from  the  Baltic  Area 
1940-44       U.S.S.R.  (Karelian  Isthmus)  to  Finland  415,000  Karelian  Finns 


d  Jewish  refugees  from  Poland  included  below  in  total  of  225,000  Jewish  refugees  from  various  countries. 

e  Rough  estimate. 

'Total  140,000;   most  went  farther  to  west  and  included  in  total  of  225,000  Jewish  refugees. 

s  In  course. 

h  Figures  according  to  the  exchange  agreement. 


358 


HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 


YEARS 


TABLE   10-1    (Cont.) 
Redistribution  of  Population  Produced  by  World  War  II 


ROUTE 


GROUP 


Population  Movements  of  Non-Germans  from  the  Baltic  Area 


1941-44 


1941-47 


1942-44 


1942-43 
1943-44 


U.S.S.R.  (Estonia,  Latvia,  Lithuania)  to 
Germany,  Austria,  and  Italy 


U.S.S.R.   (Estonia,  Latvia,  Lithuania) 
through  Germany  to  Belgium 


U.S.S.R.  (Estonia,  Latvia,  Lithuania)  to 
Sweden 


U.S.S.R.   (Estonia)  to  Sweden 
U.S.S.R.  (Leningrad  area)  to  Finland 


165,000  Estonian,  Latvian, 
and  Lithuanian 
displaced  persons 

35,000  Estonian,  Latvian, 
and  Lithuanian 
persons 

30,000  Estonian,  Latvian, 
and  Lithuanian 
refugees 
6,000  ethnic  Swedes 
18,000  Ingermanlanders ' 


Other  Population  Movements  Into  Or/And  From  Various  European  Countries 


1941 
1941 
1946 

1941-45 


1943-46 
1940-45 


Bulgaria  (southern  Dobrudja)  to  Rumania 
Rumania  ( northern  Dobrudja )  to  Bulgaria 
Greece,  Bulgaria,  Rumania  to  U.S.S.R. 

( Soviet  Armenia) 
U.S.S.R.    ( former  eastern   Poland   and   old 

Soviet    Ukraine)    to    Germany,    Austria, 

and  Italy 

Eastern  and  Central  Europe  to  Germany, 

Austria,  and  Italy 
Various   European   countries   to   Germany, 

Austria,  and  Italy 


110,000  Rumanians 
62,000  Bulgarians 
30,000  Armenians  J 


150,000  Ukrainian 
displaced  persons 

225,000  Jewish  refugees 

150,000  Displaced  persons 
and  refugees  e 


Population  Movements  Within  the  U.S.S.R. 


1941 

1941-42 

1945-46 

1946 
1946 


Volga   region   to   the   Asiatic   part   of   the 

U.S.S.B. 
Axis  occupied  Soviet  territory  to  inner  and 

Asiatic  parts  of  the  U.S.S.R. 
Southern  Russia  to  the  Asiatic  part  of 

U.S.S.R. 


Russia  proper  and  the  Ukraine  to  Crimea 
Dagestan  to  former  Chechen  land 


400,000  Volga  Germans 
1,500,000  Soviet  citizens  k  e 

600,000,  Crimean  Tartars, 

Kalmyks,  Chechen, 

and  Karachai 
50,000  Russian  and 

Ukrainian  settlers1 
60,000  Dagestan 

mountaineers 


1  Total  65,000;   the  majority  returned  to  the  U.S.S.R. 

J  Total  about   100,000 — about   70  per  cent  from  non-European  countries   (Syria,   Iran,   Lebanon). 
k  Total   number   evacuees   (partly  deportees   from   Soviet   territories)    estimated   at    12,000,000    of   whom 
great  majority  returned. 
1  First   contingent. 
*  E.  M.  Kulischer,  Europe  on  the  Move   (New  York,  Columbia  University  Press,   1948),  pp.  302-303. 


MIGRATIONS  359 


YEARS  ROUTE  CROUP 

Population  Movements  Within  the   U.S.S.R. 

1946  Various  parts  of  the  U.S.S.R.  to  southern 

Sakhalin  50,000  Russians 

1945-47  Central  and  western  Russia  proper,  Belo- 
russia,  and  Lithuania  to  Russian  East 
Prussia  500,000  Russians, 

Byelorussians,  and 
Lithuanians 
1945-47       Old    Soviet    territory   to    other    newly    ac- 
quired western  territories  of  the  U.S.S.R.  500,000  Russians, 

Ukrainians,  and 
others  e 


These  mass  movements  in  Eastern  and  Central  Europe  during  and 
after  World  War  II  have  resulted  in  a  complete  change  in  the  ethnic  and 
linguistic  composition  of  some  of  the  countries  affected  by  these  migra- 
tions as  well  as  in  a  new  balance  of  power,  or  lack  of  it,  between  their 
majorities  and  minorities. 

Poland,  for  instance,  is  now  a  country  virtually  free  of  ethnic  minorities. 
Its  German  minority  of  close  to  nine  million  before  World  War  II  has 
been  reduced,  mainly  through  expulsions,  to  approximately  one  to  two 
hundred  thousand,16  most  of  whom  live  in  the  so-called  Recovered  Terri- 
tories. Its  large  Jewish  minority  has  been  reduced,  chiefly  by  extermina- 
tion during  the  German  occupation,  to  thirty  to  thirty-five  thousand.  Of 
the  Eastern  Slavic  groups  once  residing  within  the  boundaries  of  Poland 
the  vast  majority,  mostly  Ukrainians  and  Byelorussians,  lived  east  of  the 
Curzon  line  and  are  now  outside  the  boundaries  of  Poland.  Thus  a  country 
once  confronted  with  major  minority  and  boundary  problems  due  to  large 
ethnic  minorities  is  now  ethnically  homogeneous. 

Czechoslovakia  offers  another  illustration  of  a  country  which,  plagued 
by  the  failure  to  assimilate  its  minorities  and  to  create  a  unified  national 
state,  undertook  to  solve  its  minority  question  by  mass  expulsions,  affect- 
ing in  particular  its   most  thorny  minority,   the   Germans.   Numbering 

16  The  estimates  vary  a  great  deal.  German  sources  claim  the  existence  of  much 
larger  German  groups,  in  particular  in  Upper  Silesia.  These  discrepancies  show 
vividly  the  difficulties  with  which  one  is  confronted  in  the  task  of  defining  ethnic 
frontiers.  In  border  areas,  such  as  Upper  Silesia,  one  frequently  encounters  bilingual 
groups  whose  national  loyalties  are  not  clearly  defined  and  shift  with  changing  for- 
tunes of  war  and  peace.  The  number  of  bilingual  Silesians  is  approximately  one  million. 
They  are  claimed  by  both  Poles  and  Germans— a  good  illustration  of  the  problems 
with  which  boundary-makers  are  confronted  if  attempting  to  draw  the  line  in  ac- 
cordance with  ethnic  and  linguistic  distinctions. 


GERMAN 
EXPELLEES 


Moscow 


Fig.  10-1.  Mass  Migration  of  Ethnic  Germans  into  West  Germany  After  World  War  II; 

Pomerania     891,000 

East  Prussia   1,347,000 

East  Brandenburg   131,000 

Silesia    2,053,000 

Danzig    225,000 

Memelland    48,000 

Estonia,  Latvia,  Lithuania   59,000 

Poland     410,000 

Soviet  Union    51,000 

Czechoslovakia     1,912,000 

Rumania   149,000 

Hungary    178,000 

Yugoslavia    148,000 

other  European  countries  and  from  overseas   .  .  274,000 

Soviet  Zone  and  Berlin 1,555,000 

Soviet  Zone  and  Berlin 4,000,000 


Expellees  from: 

(1) 

(2) 

(3) 

(4) 

(5) 

(6) 

(7) 

(8) 

(9) 

(10) 

(ID 

(12) 

(13) 

(14) 

Refugees  from: 

(15) 

Expellees  arrived: 

(16) 

360 


MIGRATIONS  361 

3,300,000  in  1936,  the  close-knit  German  community  of  the  Sudetenlands 
had  played  a  prominent  part  in  the  "Protectorate"  of  Bohemia  and  Mo- 
ravia during  the  Nazi  occupation.  The  expulsion  of  3,038,000  Sudeten- 
Germans  under  the  terms  of  the  Potsdam  Agreement  reduced  the  remain- 
ing German  group  in  Czechoslovakia  to  200,000.  The  vacuum  created  by 
the  mass  evacuation  was  filled  by  Czech  settlers.  But  the  presence  of  some 
two  million  Sudeten  German  expellees  in  Western  Germany,  clinging 
together  in  organizations  which  keep  Sudeten  German  irredentism  alive, 
makes  the  hastily  filled  vacuum  appear  as  a  zone  of  insecurity  and  a 
cradle  of  conflict.  The  atmosphere  of  insecurity  is  even  more  accentuated 
by  the  fact  that  the  expulsion  of  its  most  troublesome  ethnic  group  left  the 
country  still  saddled  with  the  age-old  conflict  between  Czechs  and  Slo- 
vaks. Totalling  2,400,000,  about  one-fifth  of  the  entire  population  of 
Czechoslovakia,  the  Slovaks  confront  the  country  continuously  with  prob- 
lems of  Slovak  nationalism.  Uneven  cultural  and  political  development 
between  Czechs  and  Slovaks  and  a  serious  divergence  in  religious  belief 
are  factors  explaining  the  lack  of  a  constructive  symbiosis  between 
Czechs  and  Slovaks.  Here  we  deal  with  a  minority  whose  problems  could 
not  have  been  "solved"  by  migration  or  population  transfer  and  whose 
continuous  presence  as  a  minority  with  an  intense  nationalism  has  so  far 
defied  all  efforts  to  create  a  unified  national  state. 

A  contrasting  problem  is  that  of  Germany,  which  was  forced  to  receive 
huge  masses  of  Germans  17  who  fled  or  were  expelled  from  the  East  as  a 
result  of  World  War  II  (Fig.  10-1 ).  Ten  and  a  half  million  or  21  per  cent 
of  the  total  population  of  the  German  Federal  Republic  of  forty-nine  mil- 
lion are  expellees.  These  are  divided  into  three  categories:  (1)  some  8.4 
million  expellees  from  German  provinces  east  of  the  Oder-Neisse  Line 
now  under  Polish  or  U.S.S.R.  administration,  and  from  Czechoslovakia, 
Poland,  Hungary,  Rumania,  Yugoslavia,  and  other  countries.  The  largest 
contingents  are  from  the  former  German  provinces  of  Silesia,  East  Prussia, 
Pomerania,  and  Brandenburg  (4,423,000),  and  from  Czechoslovakia 
(1,912,000);  (2)  over  two  million  persons  who  fled  to  Western  Germany 
and  are  unable  to  return  to  the  Eastern  European  areas  from  which  they 
came;  (3)  two  hundred  thousand  stateless  and  foreign  refugees.  Clearly 
the  presence  of  a  group  of  new  citizens  totalling  nearly  a  fourth  of 
West  Germany's  population  confronted  the  country  with  difficult  postwar 
adjustment  and  rehabilitation  tasks  in  the  process  of  absorbing  the  com- 
pletely destitute  millions.  As  a  West  German  government  source  put  it, 
the  situation  was  about  the  same  as  if  more  than  the  total  population  of 

17  The  figures  are  based  on  official  West  German  estimates  as  of  December  31,  1950. 


362  HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 

Denmark  and  Switzerland  combined,  or  if  considerably  more  than  the 
entire  population  of  Australia  would  have  been  compelled  to  find  accom- 
modation, work,  and  a  living  in  what  was  then  ( but  no  longer  is )  a  totally 
impoverished  Federal  Republic  of  Germany.18 

While  the  Iron  Curtain  has  sealed  off  not  only  the  West  from  the  Soviet 
Empire  but  also  the  Soviet  satellites  from  each  other,  thus  bringing  the 
mass  population  shifts  of  World  War  II  and  of  the  immediate  postwar 
period  to  a  standstill,  the  two  Germanies  separated  from  each  other  still 
experience  a  numerically  reduced  but  continuous  migration  from  eastern 
to  western  Germany  which  totalled  between  1950  and  1951  about  1,800,- 
000  or  10  per  cent  of  East  Germany's  entire  population.  Here,  as  in  the 
lands  of  eastern  Europe,  it  is  still  too  early  to  evaluate  the  far-reaching 
changes  which  the  uprooting  of  millions  has  brought  to  their  new  home- 
lands; too  early  because  the  consolidation  and  assimilation  process  is  still 
in  progress.  This  statement  should  not  detract  from  the  fact  that  in  some 
cases,  however  exceptional,  the  integration  of  the  refugees  has  met  with 
full  success.  A  case  in  point  is  Finland  which,  aided  by  the  availability  of 
cultivable  surplus  land,  succeeded  in  settling  on  the  basis  of  careful  plan- 
ning the  415,000  Karelian  Finns  (about  11  per  cent  of  its  total  population) 
who  poured  into  Finland  from  territories  ceded  to  Russia  after  the  Russo- 
Finnish  war  of  1939  to  1940.19 

In  some  parts  of  Western  Germany  the  impact  of  the  expellee  groups 
has  been  so  strong  that  it  has  radically  changed  the  sociological  structure 
of  the  region  concerned.  In  national  politics,  the  close-knit  expellee  groups 
have  become  power  factors  of  great  importance,  affecting  the  strategy  of 
the  political  parties  and  making  their  irredentist  claims  a  matter  of  con- 
cern for  the  country  as  a  whole.  Furthermore  the  influx  of  refugees  dras- 
tically changed  the  religious  composition  of  West  Germany.  In  the  past, 
the  map  showing  the  geographical  distribution  of  religions  revealed  a 
pattern  of  clearly  discernible  Protestant  and  Catholic  areas  with  political 
leanings  strongly  influenced  by  confessional  issues.  The  mass  migrations 
have  broken  up  this  pattern  and  the  denominations  are  much  more  mixed 
geographically  than  formerly. 

Poland,  Czechoslovakia,  and  Germany  offer  the  most  impressive  ex- 
amples in  the  European  theatre  of  mass  migrations  in  the  wake  of  World 
War  II.  But  a  glance  at  Kulischer's  list  of  flights  and  transfers  of  popula- 
tions in  Europe  and  the  U.S.S.R.  during  and  after  World  War  II  shows 

18  For  further  details,  see  C.  D.  Harris  and  G.  Wuelker,  "The  Refugee  Problem  in 
Germany,"  Economic  Geography  (1953),  pp.  10-25. 
is  See  p.  241. 


MIGRATIONS  363 

clearly  the  uprooting  of  the  human  structure  of  all  the  lands  of  central 
and  eastern  Europe.  These  wanderings  differ  basically  from  the  great 
overseas  migrations  between  1870  and  1920.  The  war  and  postwar  mass 
migrations  were  not  motivated  by  the  pioneer  spirit  of  individuals  and 
groups  but  by  fear  and  coercion.  The  mass  migrations  of  our  time  are 
"the  flight  of  millions  from  their  wrecked  homes,  the  mass  exodus  of 
people  haunted  by  fear,  the  mass  shipment  of  human  beings  to  destruc- 
tion. Measured  by  the  number  of  persons  affected,  these  recent  shifts  of 
population  have  been  of  the  magnitude  of  the  economic  migration  of  the 
whole  preceding  century."  20 

Population  Transfers  in  Asia.  While  we  have  given  prominence  to  the 
treatment  of  population  movements  in  eastern  and  western  Europe,  it 
must  be  realized  that  they  represent  only  one  among  numerous  other 
equally  disorganized  major  population  displacements  which  originated 
during,  or  as  the  result  of  the  World  Wars.  In  1921,  Walter  Duranty  noted 
in  Moscow:  "One  of  the  strangest  features  of  Russian  life  today  is  the 
wanderers— wandering  children,  wandering  soldiers,  wandering  families, 
wandering  villages,  wandering  tribes— driven  from  their  homes  by  the 
war  or  revolution  to  move  interminably  across  the  vast  Russian  plains."  21 
This  characterization  was  to  hold  true  for  many  years  to  come  and  again 
after  World  War  II.  We  find  it  equally  true  for  many  other  danger  spots 
on  the  globe,  whether  as  the  result  of  India's  partition  and  the  migrations 
this  caused,  or  of  China's  flood  and  drought  areas,  resulting  periodically 
in  mass  movements,  or  of  South  East  Asia's  migration  of  Chinese  and 
Indians  across  international  frontiers,  or  of  Manchuria's  and  Japan's  wan- 
dering nationals,  testifying  to  the  ambition  and  collapse  of  Japan's 
"Greater  Asian  Co-Prosperity  Sphere." 

Within  the  span  of  a  few  months,  the  Partition  of  India  of  August  15, 
1947  prompted  mass  migrations  "on  a  scale  absolutely  unparalleled  in  the 
history  of  the  world."  22  The  communal  riots  started  in  the  Indo-Gangetic 
Plains,  in  the  Punjab  area  which  covers  55,000  square  miles.  Accompanied 
by  appalling  bloodshed,  the  final  balance  sheet  showed  in  March  1948 
that  six  and  a  half  million  Moslems  had  fled  into  West  Pakistan,  while 
about  six  million  Hindus  and  Sikhs  had  left  it.  New  disorders  in  Bengal 
between  1948  and  1950  started  another  wave  of  mass  population  move- 

20  Woytinsky,  op.  cit.,  p.  110. 

21  Kulischer,  op.  cit.,  p.  30. 

22  O.  H.  K.  Spate,  "India  and  Pakistan,"  A  General  and  Regional  Geography 
(London  and  New  York,  1954),  p.  110;  the  discussion,  above,  of  the  1947,  1948,  and 
consequent  migrations  is  based  on  Spate's  account,  op.  cit.,  pp.  118-120;  see  also  the 
bibliographical  notes  on  pp.  121,  481  f. 


364  HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 

ments,  during  which  about  three  and  a  half  million  people  left  East  Pakis- 
tan and  one  million  Moslems  entered  it.  What  distinguishes  this  movement 
from  that  in  the  Punjab  and  West  Pakistan  is  that  the  Bengal  wave  swept 
in  one  direction  only  until  1950,  carrying  Hindus  on  their  flight  from  East 
Bengal  into  Indian  territory;  in  1950,  the  mass  influx  of  these  refugees 
generated  a  counterwave  of  Moslems  into  Pakistan.  "The  total  movement 
is  thus  of  the  order  of  seventeen  million,"  twice  the  population  of  Greater 
London,  New  York  City,  or  Tokyo.23  "No  comparable  event  has  ever  been 
known."  24 

Clearly  these  mass  migrations,  and  in  their  wake  the  critical  tasks  of 
rehabilitation  and  resettlement  of  the  uprooted  millions,  have  affected 
deeply  the  political,  social,  and  cultural  structure  of  both  India  and  Pakis- 
tan, thus  confronting  the  student  of  political  geography  with  a  radically 
different  political  and  social  landscape  and  the  two  countries  with  many 
problems,  most  of  which  are  still  awaiting  solution.  According  to  Spate's 
analysis,  the  population  transfers  have  not  perhaps  modified  greatly  the 
general  distribution  of  population,  except  to  swell  the  larger  towns  of  the 
north,  but  they  have  altered  profoundly  the  communal  pattern.  For  in- 
stance, the  Indian  government,  in  its  resettlement  program,  has  plans  for 
eighteen  new  townships;  by  March,  1950,  four  million  acres  of  reclaimed 
and  evacuee  land  were  allotted  to  390,000  families,  or  a  total  of  about  two 
million  people;  the  population  of  Delhi  included  in  1950  24  per  cent 
refugees— the  intrusive  minorities  were  largely  urban,  which  fact  posed 
special  problems  to  the  overcrowded  and  unsanitary  cities.25  Thus  the 
manifold  problems  of  resettlement  and  the  instability  which  the  overflow 
of  refugees  has  brought  to  India  and  Pakistan  since  the  Partition  of  1947 
are  still,  almost  a  decade  later,  a  major  characteristic  of  the  internal  politi- 
cal geography  of  the  subcontinent. 

A  mass  displacement  of  comparable  political  importance  was  created 
by  the  warfare  connected  with  the  creation  of  Israel  in  1948.  Several 
hundred  thousand  Arabs  fled  or  were  uprooted  from  their  homes  in  the 
territory  of  the  new  state.  Since  that  time  these  refugees  have  been 
maintained  in  miserable  camps  through  the  largesse  of  an  international 
organization  created  by  the  United  Nations  for  this  purpose. 

These  camps  are  generally  located  dangerously  near  the  borders  of 
Israel  in  the  Gaza  strip  (Egypt),  in  Jordan,  and  in  Syria.  Very  few  of  the 

23  London  (1951):  8,346,000;  New  York's  five  boroughs  (1950):  7,892,000; 
Tokyo  (1954):  7,736,000. 

24  Spate,  op.  cit.,  p.  119. 

25  Ibid.,  p.  120. 


MIGRATIONS  365 

Arab  refugees  have  been  integrated  in  the  economies  of  the  countries  in 
which  they  live.  After  almost  a  decade  of  refugee  life  the  800  thousand 
Arabs  under  international  care  still  hope  to  recover  their  lands.  They  are 
a  persistent  source  of  border  conflict  and  international  incidents  in  the 
troubled  relations  between  Israel  and  her  neighbors. 

Great  displacements  of  population  are  therefore  not  a  monopolv  of 
Europe,  though  it  is  in  that  continent  that  they  have  been  most  systemati- 
cally carried  through. 

THE  WESTWARD  THRUST  IN  EUROPE 

The  preceding  sections  have  described  the  forced  migrations  succes- 
sively connected  with  Nazi  aggressions,  the  war,  and  postwar  territorial  re- 
visions. The  redistribution  of  population  incident  to  the  second  World  War 
brought  about  the  permanent  migration  of  close  to  thirty  million  people, 
which  Eugene  M.  Kulischer  has  described  as  probably  the  greatest  migra- 
tion in  European  history.  In  any  event,  it  has  remade  the  map  of  popula- 
tion and  ethnic  distribution  in  central  Europe.  In  essence  this  migration 
has  been  a  great  westward  movement  induced  by  the  collapse  of  Ger- 
many. Though  there  have  been  significant  displacements  of  population 
affecting  every  country  east  of  the  Rhine,  the  overall  pattern  is  of  a  west- 
ward push  of  populations  before  the  thrust  of  Slavic  victories  in  the  east. 

Dominating  the  picture  is  the  tremendously  important  expansion  of 
Slav  at  the  expense  of  Teuton.  In  this  respect  European  history  has  been 
turned  back  almost  a  thousand  years,  when  Slavic  settlement  extended 
from  the  Baltic  to  the  Adriatic,  as  far  west  as  the  present  Iron  Curtain. 
Some  eleven  million  Germans  have  been  forced  back  into  the  rump  terri- 
tory of  Germandom.  Almost  every  eastern  European  country  has  liqui- 
dated its  German  minority  or  reduced  it  to  a  small  fraction  of  its  former 
size.  The  main  German  settlement  area  has  been  driven  back  to  the  Oder- 
Neisse  line. 

Into  the  vacuum  have  poured  millions  of  Slavs,  particularly  Poles  and 
Czechs,  who  themselves  have  been  divested  of  territory  by  the  Soviet 
Union.  Only  a  small  fraction  of  this  enormous  movement  has  gone  on  into 
western  Europe  and  overseas.  The  problem  of  economic  and  cultural 
assimilation  of  this  enormous  mass  of  refugees  is  one  of  the  most  difficult 
facing  Europe  today. 

Yet  from  the  economic  point  of  view  it  is  well  on  the  way  to  solution. 

The  underlying  demographic  and  economic  pressures  from  East  to 
West  have  been  greatly  reduced  by  the  territorial  changes  resulting  from 


366  HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 

the  war.  In  terms  of  the  measure  of  density  of  the  agricultural  population, 
and  considering  the  relative  change  in  population  as  compared  with  that 
of  Europe  as  a  whole  in  the  period  of  1939  to  1954,  Poland  has  increased 
its  relative  agricultural  living  space  about  60  per  cent  and  Czechoslovakia 
by  about  one-fourth.  In  both  cases  this  result  was  partly  due  to  war  deaths 
but  chiefly  to  the  expulsion  of  some  thirteen  million  inhabitants  from  the 
present  territories  of  these  countries.  Both  are  now  better  off  than  the 
European  average. 

The  Danubian  countries,  on  the  other  hand,  were  not  so  favored  in  the 
redistribution  of  population  and  their  position  has  not  been  so  markedly 
improved.  In  relation  to  European  averages  the  Yugoslavs,  Rumanians, 
and  Hungarians  are  nevertheless  almost  certainly  in  a  relatively  better 
position  in  terms  of  agricultural  density  of  population  than  before  the 
war,  owing  to  war  losses  and  to  expulsion  of  ethnic  minorities.  Quite 
aside  from  these  gains,  events  have  spared  these  countries  the  additional 
population  pressure  ( relative  to  the  European  average )  that  would  prob- 
ably otherwise  have  occurred.26 

The  reduction  of  population  pressure  in  these  countries  is  also  being 
promoted  by  ( a )  urbanization  and  industrialization,  and  ( b )  the  present 
results  of  rapid  declines  in  the  birth  rate  that  occurred  in  the  interwar 
period.  The  one  factor  is  increasing  employment  opportunities,  the  other 
is  reducing  the  competition  for  available  jobs  and  for  the  land.  In  most 
Eastern  European  countries  the  number  of  young  people  entering  work 
ages  (that  is,  age  fifteen  to  twenty)  is  declining  each  year  as  a  result  of 
the  fall  in  the  birth  rate  that  occurred  fifteen  to  twenty  years  ago.  This 
source  of  pressure  on  employment  opportunities  is  considerably  reduced. 

Quite  apart  from  its  ideologies,  Eastern  Europe  is  moving  into  the 
demographic  and  economic  situation  that  earlier  brought  relief  from 
population  pressures  in  Western  Europe,  and  of  course  in  so  doing  it  has 
liquidated  important  minority  problems. 

But  what  of  the  countries  that  had  to  absorb  the  dispossessed  of  the 
East?  In  practice  this  means  Germany  since  other  Western  countries  have 
received  far  smaller  contingents. 

The  war  added  one-fourth  to  the  already  crowded  population  of  West 
Germany.  The  refugees  came  in  enormous  numbers  and  without  resources 
into  a  land  amputated  by  political  partition  and  with  the  shattered 
economy  of  a  beaten  nation.  The  prognosis  was  certainly  poor.  But  to  the 
amazement  of  many  observers  West  Germany  has  already  gone  far  toward 

26  Cf.  F.  W.  Notestein  et  al.,  The  Future  Population  of  Europe  and  the  Soviet 
Union  (Geneva,  1944). 


MIGRATIONS  367 

effective  absorption  of  its  refugees.  Economic  output  is  now  far  above  the 
best  achieved  before  the  war  and  under  Hitler.  Even  per  capita  income 
is  now  well  above  prewar  levels  and  is  increasing  rapidly. 

It  is  now  clear  that  the  presence  of  the  refugees  is  actually  contributing 
to  the  more  sustained  economic  progress  of  Germany  as  compared  with 
neighboring  countries.  The  refugees  provided  a  reserve  of  skilled,  indus- 
trious labor  lacking  in  other  Western  European  countries  where,  except 
for  Italy,  early  gains  brought  about  full  employment  of  the  available 
labor  force. 

These  aggregate  developments  do  not  mean  that  the  individual  refugee 
in  Germany  is  better  off  than  before  the  war.  But  they  do  mean  that  the 
refugee  burden  has  not  been  an  insuperable  one  and  that  in  fact  it  is  now 
being  turned  to  advantage.  The  extent  of  this  success  may  be  measured 
by  the  fact  that  German  leaders,  far  from  seeking  emigration  outlets  for 
"surplus"  population,  are  now  exploring  possibilities  for  bringing  in  Italian 
and  other  workers  to  provide  part  of  the  labor  needed  to  support  re- 
armament. 

POSTWAR  MIGRATIONS  AFFECTING  THE  EUROPEAN 

SETTLEMENT  AREA 

Since  World  War  II  there  has  been  a  substantial  revival  of  overseas 
migration  from  Europe  2T  (Fig.  10-2).  Much  of  this  is  related  to  war  dis- 
placements of  population.  But  the  publicity  attending  the  more  dramatic 
refugee  movements  has  obscured  the  resurgence  of  voluntary  "free"  mi- 
grations such  as  those  that  peopled  North  America,  Australasia,  and  large 
parts  of  South  America  from  Europe  in  the  last  two  centuries. 

Since  the  war  at  least  five  million  persons  have  emigrated  from  Europe, 
a  mass  migration  exceeding  the  total  population  of  Switzerland.  In  the 
average  postwar  year  about  650,000  emigrants  were  recorded  as  leaving 
Europe  for  countries  overseas,  and  the  actual  figure  was  undoubtedly 
larger.  "Return"  migration  amounts  to  about  one-third  of  this  total.  The 
identifiable  net  outward  movement  in  the  period  1946  to  1952  was  3.2 
million  or  about  450,000  per  year.  This  substantial  movement  represents 

27  Department  of  State,  Office  of  Intelligence  Research,  Survey  of  Overseas  Emi- 
gration from  Europe,  1946-51.  Unclassified  Intelligence  Report  6054,  May,  1953.  For 
prewar  materials  this  summary  also  draws  heavily  on  earlier  studies  of  migration  bv 
D.  Kirk;  Europe's  Population  in  the  Interwar  Years  (Geneva,  1946),  Chs.  4-7; 
"European  Migrations:  Prewar  Trends  and  Future  Prospects,"  Milbank  Memorial 
Fund  Quarterly,  Vol.  25,  No.  225  (April,  1947);  and  "Overseas  Migration  from 
Europe  Since  World  War  II,"  American  Sociological  Review,  Vol.  19,  No.  4  (August, 
1954),  pp.  447-56.  Portions  of  the  last-named  article,  written  by  Dudley  Kirk  and 
Earl  Huyck,  are  included  in  the  present  text. 


Fig.  10-2.  Net  Postwar  Overseas  Migration,  Europe  1946-52  (in  thousands). 


368 


MIGRATIONS  369 

the  highest  figures  reached  since  the  application  of  severe  restrictive 
measures  by  the  United  States  in  the  early  1920's.  In  gross  volume  it  is 
comparable  to  European  emigration  from  1880  to  1900.  It  has  not,  how- 
ever, attained  the  huge  totals  registered  immediately  prior  to  World 
War  I. 

Overseas  migration  drained  off  approximately  one-eighth  of  the  natural 
growth  of  population  in  Europe  since  the  war,  as  compared  with  about 
one-fifth  removed  by  the  maximum  movements  in  the  years  1900  to  1914. 

Much  of  the  controversy  concerning  migration  restrictions  in  the  United 
States  and  other  countries  of  immigration  has  revolved  around  the  dis- 
placement of  "old"  migration  from  Northwest  Europe  by  the  "new"  mi- 
gration from  Southern  and  Eastern  Europe,  a  displacement  which  came 
to  dominate  overseas  emigration  around  the  turn  of  the  century.  Trends  in 
"gross"  emigration  from  the  chief  regions  and  countries  of  origin  are 
shown  in  Table  10-2. 

The  pattern  of  "gross"  emigration  resembles  that  of  the  1920's.  The 
United  Kingdom,  Germany,  Italy,  Spain,  and  Portugal  each  recorded  a 
roughly  parallel  emigration  in  the  two  periods,  both  in  numbers  and  in 
percentages  of  the  European  total.  Gross  emigration  from  Eastern  Europe 
was  higher  than  in  the  1920's  but  much  lower  than  at  the  turn  of  the 
century.  The  other  major  difference  is  the  new  emigration  from  the  Neth- 
erlands, which  is  chiefly  responsible  for  the  rise  in  the  joint  figure  for 
France  and  the  Low  Countries. 

The  pattern  of  "net"  emigration  is  somewhat  different  because  of  the 
large  return  migration,  particularly  to  the  United  Kingdom,  to  the  Neth- 
erlands, and  to  Spain  and  Portugal.  The  total  net  emigration  by  country 
of  origin  and  destination  is  shown  in  Tables  10-3  and  4.  The  leading  coun- 
tries are  the  United  Kingdom  and  Italy  (over  600,000  each),  Poland 
(460,000),  Germany  (290,000),  U.S.S.R.  (230,000),  Spain  and  Portugal 
(180,000  each),  and  Rumania  (160,000).  Some  three  hundred  thousand 
Dutch  emigrated  overseas  since  the  war  but  these  were  largely  offset  by 
repatriations  and  other  immigration  from  Indonesia.  France  was  the  only 
European  country  of  overseas  "immigration,"  which  resulted  from  the  mass 
migration  of  North  Africans  to  the  metropole. 

As  in  the  latter  days  of  unrestricted  migration,  the  leading  sources  were 
in  Eastern  and  Southern  Europe.  Of  the  eight  countries  supplying  over 
a  hundred  thousand  emigrants  since  the  war,  six  were  in  these  regions. 
Certain  older  areas  of  emigration,  such  as  Ireland  and  Scandinavia,  were 
notably  underrepresented.  Irish  emigration  now  goes  almost  wholly  to 
Britain  rather  than  overseas. 


370  HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 


TABLE  10-2 


Gross  Overseas  Emigration  from  Europe,  1901-52 
(Annual  Average  in  Thousands) 


1901-10 

1911-20 

1921-30 

1931-40 

1946-52  a 

Regions  of  Old  Emigration 

British  Isles 
Germany 
Scandinavia 

France,  Low  Countries, 
Switzerland 

195 
27 
49 

16 

183 

9 

20 

12 

180 
56 

25 

13 

32 

15 

4 

5 

165 
40 
12 

63  b 

Regions  of  New  Emigration 

Italy 

Portugal,  Spain 

Eastern  Europe  c 

362 
142 
447 

219 
171 
271 

110 
86 

123 

26 
23 
34 

107 

74 
188 

Total 

1,238 

885 

593 

139 

649 

Percent  "old"  emigration 
Percent  "new"  emigration 

23 

77 

26 

74 

47 
53 

40 
60 

43 
57 

a  For  a  number  of  individual  countries,   average  for   the  years   1946-51. 

b  Excluding  movement  of  Algerian  workers  returning  to  Algeria  from  France,  estimated  to  average  53,000 
per  year  in   1946-51,  inclusive. 

c  Including  Austria,    Finland,    Greece,   Yugoslavia,   and   Soviet  Orbit. 


While  the  United  States  has  continued  to  be  the  leading  destination  of 
European  migration,  it  does  not  hold  the  commanding  position  that  it  did 
in  the  days  of  unrestricted  movement,  when  the  United  States  was  receiv- 
ing from  a  half  to  two-thirds  of  all  European  emigrants  (cf.  Fig.  10-2). 
Since  the  war  the  United  States  has  played  host  to  only  about  one-third 
(950,000)  of  the  net  movement,  while  Canada,  Australia,  and  Argentina 
have  each  absorbed  well  over  half  a  million.  Australia  in  particular  has 
been  receiving  immigrants  at  a  ratio  to  population  far  exceeding  that  for 
the  United  States  even  at  its  greatest  period  of  immigration.  Immigration 
to  Australia  and  Canada  has  been  chiefly  drawn  from  among  British  sub- 
jects and  other  Northwest  Europeans  on  the  one  hand  and  displaced  per- 
sons on  the  other,  with  limited  numbers  from  other  sources.  Argentinian 
immigration  has  been  almost  wholly  from  Italy  and  Spain,  with  less  than 
ten  per  cent  of  the  total  being  displaced  persons.  About  half  of  the  United 
States  immigrants  were  displaced  persons  admitted  under  special  legisla- 
tion; the  remainder  follow  in  the  order  of  magnitude  of  the  quotas,  which 
favor  immigrants  from  Northwest  Europe. 

The  final  major  country  of  immigration  is  Israel,  which  alone  in  the 
postwar  period  owes  its  existence  as  an  independent  nation  to  large-scale 
immigration.  The  370,000  Jews  from  all  parts  of  Europe  for  whom  it 


MIGRATIONS  371 

provided  a  refuge  have  contributed  spectacularly  in  establishing  the 
demographic  base  for  the  Jewish  state— the  new  immigrants  constituted 
43  per  cent  of  the  total  population  at  the  end  of  1951.  The  days  of  large- 
scale  "rescue  migration"  appear  to  be  over,  however,  for  only  23,000 
arrived  in  1952  as  compared  with  191,000  in  the  previous  year. 

In  the  receiving  country  immigrants  went  primarily  to  the  urban  areas. 
Immigrants  into  the  United  States  in  1952,  for  example,  went  overwhelm- 
ingly into  the  cities— nearly  three-fifths  into  the  big  cities  of  a  hundred 
thousand  or  over,  27  per  cent  into  other  urban  areas,  and  only  the  small 
remainder  into  the  rural  areas.  Over  one-half  of  the  1952  arrivals  in 
Canada  went  to  Ontario,  the  most  industrialized  province,  one-fifth  went 
to  Quebec,  and  only  about  one-sixth  went  westward  to  the  prairie  prov- 
inces. 

Of  the  immigrants  arriving  in  Australia  from  1947  through  1951  only 
18  per  cent  classified  themselves  as  farm  workers,  and  the  flow  of  immi- 
grants has  gone  almost  exclusively  to  the  cities.  Similarly,  in  Israel,  only 
one-fourth  of  those  permanently  settled  had  gone  into  agriculture.  The 
traditional  policy  in  Latin  America  of  putting  immigrants  on  the  land  has 
generally  been  unsuccessful,  and  there  has  been  a  pronounced  drift  to 
the  cities  in  search  of  better  employment  even  where  initial  settlement 
was  made  on  the  land. 

Prior  to  World  War  I  emigrants  left  Europe  as  individuals  without 
governmental  assistance.  Since  World  War  II,  two-fifths  of  all  European 
emigrants  have  been  moved  with  governmental  or  international  assist- 
ance. Despite  the  greater  element  of  government  control  and  assistance 
in  the  postwar  period  the  self-financed,  individual  migrant  is  still  the 
predominant  type,  whether  in  the  United  States  or  in  the  overseas  coun- 
tries as  a  whole.  With  the  liquidation  of  the  most  immediate  refugee  prob- 
lems individual  migration  is  now  a  growing  part  of  the  total. 

Almost  all  of  the  postwar  migrants  of  Eastern  European  origin  ( about 
one  million)  were  either  displaced  persons  or  refugees  from  Communism 
—by  definition,  since  countries  in  the  Soviet  orbit  now  generally  prohibit 
emigration  except  in  special  circumstances,  such  as  the  expulsion  of  ethnic 
Germans  and  of  Jews  from  satellite  countries. 

Although  motivated  by  political  oppression,  this  movement  was  none- 
theless in  accord  with  underlying  economic  and  demographic  forces.  The 
great  displacements  of  population  in  Central  and  Eastern  Europe  have 
been  successful  precisely  because  they  were  in  accord  with  population 
pressures  from  East  to  West.  Conversely  German  efforts  to  colonize  the 
East  were  unsuccessful  essentially  because  the  educated,  urbanized  Ger- 


372  HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 

man  could  not  compete  effectively  for  the  land  against  the  prolific, 
peasant  Slav.  Similarly,  the  displaced  persons  from  the  Soviet  Union  were 
not  Great  Russians  but  chiefly  more  advanced  peoples  thrust  aside  by  the 
westward  push  of  the  Russians— the  Baltic  peoples,  the  Poles,  and  the 
Jews.  In  this  regard  the  movement  paralleled  the  "Russian"  emigration  of 
the  early  part  of  the  century— actually  largely  a  migration  of  these  same 
minority  peoples  from  the  old  Russian  Empire. 

TABLE  10-3 

Net  Emigration  from  Europe,  1946-52:  Western  and  Southern  Europe  * 

(in  Thousands) 


< 

O 

►j 

M 

z 

-t 

AREA  OF 
IMMIGRATION 

CO 

w 

> 

< 
g 

s 

z 

< 

> 
z 
< 
S 

PS 

< 

H 
a 
W 

a 

H 

W 

w 
o 
Z 
< 

> 

< 
o 
P 

H 
PS 

z 

< 

w 

o 
w 
ta 

H 
> 

< 

Ifl 

o 
o 

9 

PS 
H 

W 

< 

5 

u 

W 

« 

H 

O 

CL. 

PS 

p 

H 

O 

pq 

cfi 

0 

z 

h 

hH 

P. 

09 

o 

>l 

O 

H 

North  America 

Canada 

189 

11 

63 

63 

17 

61 

* 

1 

6 

12 

47 

470 

U.S.A. 

170 

26 

180 

18 

23 

66 

5 

2 

17 

39 

52 

598 

Latin  America 

Argentina 

1 

* 

9 

* 

2 

314 

7 

141 

* 

10 

5 

489 

Brazil 

2 

* 

9 

2 

3 

49 

95 

6 

1 

1 

6 

174 

Venezuela 

* 

# 

* 

* 

* 

61 

7 

13 

* 

2 

3 

86 

Other  d 

1 

4 

1 

20 

* 

17 

2 

18 

* 

2 

9 

74 

Africa 

South  Africa 

70 

* 

6 

14 

1 

6 

* 

* 

1 

* 

4 

102 

Other  e 

35 

1 

* 

2 

—  193 

—  1 

59 

* 

* 

* 

4 

—  93 

Asia  * 

—65 

* 

8 

—  111 

3 

2 

1 

* 

3 

8 

6 

-145 

Oceania 

Australia 

225 

2 

16 

40 

3 

68 

* 

* 

11 

24 

17 

406 

New  Zealand 

47 

* 

* 

9 

* 

* 

* 

* 

* 

1 

12 

69 

TOTAL 

675 

44 

292 

57 

—  141 

643 

176 

181 

'  39 

99 

165 

2,230 

a  Including  40,000  from  Ireland  chiefly  to  U.S.A. 

b  Including  Denmark  (17,000),  Norway  (15,000)  and  Sweden  (12,000);  all  primarily  to  North  America. 

<-■  Including  Austria  (35,000),  Belgium  (30,000),  Finland  (11,000),  Switzerland  (19,000),  generally  to 
North  America. 

d  Primarily  Netherlands  to  Surinam,  Italy  to  Uruguay  and  Peru,  Spain  to  Cuba. 

e  Chiefly:  34,000  British  to  So.  Rhodesia,  Algerian  workers  to  France,  Portuguese  to  dependences 
(notably  Angola  and  Mozambique). 

f  Primarily  Israel — net  movement  of  119,000  from  Indonesia  to  Netherlands  and  68,000  from  India 
and  Pakistan  to  the  British  Isles. 

*  The  international  migration  statistics  presented  in  this  table  are  derived  from  European,  overseas,  and 
international  sources,  all  of  which  are  in  varying  degrees  incomplete,  inaccurate,  and  inconsistent.  Since 
there  generally  is  better  recording  of  arrivals  than  of  departures,  this  table  is  in  principle  based  on  the 
statistics  of  the  receiving  country,  i.e.,  the  country  receiving  the  outward-bound  migrants  from  Europe 
as  immigrants,  and  the  European  country  receiving  the  repatriates.  Statistics  of  the  country  of  emi- 
gration combined  with  those  of  the  International  Refugee  Organization  (IRO)  and  the  Inter-govern- 
mental Committee  for  European  Migration  (ICEM)  have  been  used  where  data  of  the  receiving  country 
either  are  not  compiled,  are  incomplete,  or  unavailable  (notably  Argentina,  Brazil,  Venezuela,  Indonesia, 
India  and  Pakistan).  Wherever  possible  "country  of  birth"  data  employed  in  classification;  elsewhere, 
residence  or  political  nationality. 

The  free  world  had  another  type  of  migration  of  European  "displaced 
persons."  Whereas  much  of  Eastern  Europe  was  integrated  closely  into 
the  Soviet  security  bloc,  much  of  Asia  achieved  full  independence  with 
a  displacement  of  the  former  colonial  administrators.  The  flow  back  to 


MIGRATIONS  373 

the  mother  countries,  particularly  from  India  and  Pakistan  to  the  United 
Kingdom  (110,000)  and  from  Indonesia  to  the  Netherlands  (230,000;, 
represented  the  return  of  long-term  administrators,  businessmen,  their 
families  and  associates.  The  immigration  into  the  Netherlands  also  in- 
cluded a  number  of  Eurasians  whose  positions  in  Indonesia  had  been 
jeopardized  by  native  nationalism. 


TABLE 

10-4 

Net  Emigration  from  Europe,  1946-52:  The  Soviet  E 

uropean 

Orbit 

(in  Thousands) 

AREA  OF 
IMMIGRATION 

< 

s 

< 

c 

P 
m 

< 

i-i 

< 
> 

o 
►J 

w 
O 

n 

o 

w 

N 

> 

< 
O 

z 

p 

X 

Q 

z 

< 
1-1 

o 
a, 

< 

< 

2 

P 

OS 

{/> 
en 
P 

H 

H 
> 
o 
(/J 

H    B 

o  cc 
f-i   o 

□ 

<    B. 
H    g 

is  - 

j   8 
<:  h 

2  c 

<  w 

O    P 

North  America 

Canada 

1 

10 

9 

77 

6 

31 

134 

470 

604 

U.S.A. 

1 

28 

22 

169 

14 

120 

354 

598 

952 

Latin  America 

Argentina 

ft 

1 

3 

13 

1 

6 

24 

489 

513 

Brazil 

* 

1 

2 

4 

1 

1 

9 

174 

183 

Venezuela 

*' 

1 

2 

3 

8 

4 

10 

86 

96 

Other 

» 

o 

1 

3 

* 

4 

8 

74 

82 

Africa 

South  Africa 

* 

* 

* 

* 

ft 

» 

0 

102 

102 

Other 

o 

ft 

8 

» 

* 

* 

ft 

-  93 

-93 

Asia  ( inc.  Israel )  38 

22 

18 

121 

134 

9 

342 

-145 

197 

Oceania 

Australia 

1 

11 

13 

71 

2 

55 

153 

406 

559 

New  Zealand 

e 

«-. 

o 

1 

1 

1 

3 

69 

72 

TOTAL 

41 

74 

70 

462 

159 

231 

1037 

2230 

3267 

But  who  were  the  majority  of  the  European  emigrants  who  were  not 
displaced  persons  or  refugees?  They  were  individuals  and  families  im- 
pelled by  economic  motives  to  seek  their  fortunes  abroad  in  the  traditional 
manner.  Few  of  them  sought  land,  which  ceased  to  be  the  chief  lure  to 
overseas  migrants  generations  ago.  The  typical  postwar  migrant  was 
neither  a  farmer  nor  did  he  aspire  to  become  one.  He  rather  sought  out 
and  often  was  assisted  by  his  relatives  and  friends  in  New  York,  Toronto, 
Sydney,  Buenos  Aires,  or  Sao  Paulo.  Even  if  he  had  been  a  farmer  in  Italy 
or  Portugal  his  was  an  essentially  rural-urban  migration  across  the  seas. 
He  would  indeed  be  foolish  to  exchange  his  status  as  a  poor  tenant  on  an 
Italian  "latifundium,"  for  example,  for  an  even  worse  fate  as  a  plantation 


374  HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 

laborer  on  a  Brazilian  "fazenda."  But  this  in  principle  is  what  many  in 
countries  of  immigration  would  have  him  do— to  settle  empty  lands  and 
to  do  jobs  that  natives  are  reluctant  to  undertake  for  sound  economic 
reasons. 

The  immigrant  naturally  has  sought  his  own  kind,  where  problems  of 
personal  adjustment  are  fewest.  If  an  Englishman,  he  followed  the  flag 
to  English-speaking  lands  overseas.  If  Italian,  he  will  be  found  first  of  all 
in  Argentina  where  the  Italian  tongue  is  almost  as  well  understood  as 
Spanish.  If  Portuguese,  he  will  be  found  almost  entirely  in  Brazil  and  the 
Portuguese  colonies;  if  Spanish,  almost  exclusively  in  Latin  America. 
These  "natural"  movements  still  constitute  the  bulk  of  overseas  migration. 
It  is  the  cross-cultural  refugee  movements,  involving  major  changes  in 
language  and  customs,  that  have  created  the  acute  need  for  formal  inter- 
vention by  governments  and  international  agencies. 

Overseas  emigration  historically  served  Europe  in  two  ways:  (1)  it 
afforded  a  relief  from  population  pressure  and  an  outlet  for  the  discon- 
tented and  oppressed;  (2)  it  strengthened  ties  with  overseas  countries, 
whether  these  bonds  were  political,  economic,  or  cultural. 

The  revival  of  emigration  in  the  postwar  period  has  certainly  contrib- 
uted to  the  solution  of  European  refugee  problems.  The  successful  liqui- 
dation of  the  displaced  persons  problem  was  possible  only  through  this 
recourse.  While  emigration  has  fallen  short  of  objectives  in  some  over- 
populated  countries,  it  is  nevertheless  contributing  significantly  to  the 
solution  of  unemployment  and  underemployment  in  Southern  Europe. 
For  countries  living  in  postwar  austerity,  such  as  Britain,  emigration  has 
been  alternative  to  living  under  a  rationed  economy. 

The  great  free  migrations  before  World  War  I  were  an  integral  part  of 
the  expansion  of  Europe.  They  provided  the  human  sinews  of  European 
colonization  and  empire.  Where  they  were  not  an  instrument  of  European 
political  expansion  they  promoted  trade,  capital  movements,  and  cultural 
ties  that  enhanced  European  influence  in  the  world. 

European  colonization  of  new  lands  is  no  longer  a  major  aspect  of 
European  migration  unless  the  Jewish  settlement  of  Israel  could  be  so 
regarded.  The  vast  majority  of  emigrants  now  go  to  areas  already  occu- 
pied by  populations  of  European  race.  This  is  true  even  in  Latin  America 
—at  least  three-fourths  of  all  European  immigrants  to  this  region  went  to 
Argentina  or  to  the  predominantly  European  regions  of  Southern  Brazil. 

The  most  important  exception,  aside  from  the  dubious  case  of  Israel, 
was  the  European  immigration  into  Africa  south  of  the  Sahara,  a  net 
movement  of  at  least  two  hundred  thousand  chiefly  of  British,  Portuguese, 


MIGRATIONS  375 

and  French  administrators,  entrepreneurs,  and  settlers  in  their  respective 
territories.  The  Boer-controlled  government  of  South  Africa  officially  en- 
courages the  immigration  of  Dutch  and  Germans,  but  the  chief  effect  of 
Boer  policies  has  been  to  greatly  reduce  immigration  from  the  British 
Isles  and  to  stimulate  a  movement  of  British  to  Southern  Rhodesia.  In  no 
case,  however,  was  the  migration  sufficient  to  create  a  European  majority 
even  in  local  areas,  or  to  change  materially  the  minority  position  of  Euro- 
peans in  every  country  south  of  the  Sahara. 

The  huge  British  emigration,  500,000  of  which  has  gone  to  member 
states  of  the  Commonwealth,  has  certainly  strengthened  the  ties  that  hold 
together  this  loose  association. 

In  fact,  awareness  of  immigration  and  emigration  trends  within  the 
British  Commonwealth  of  Nations  is  an  indispensable  tool  for  an  appraisal 
of  its  changing  human  structure.  Since  1945,  Britain  has  pursued  a  vigor- 
ous policy  to  encourage  emigration  to  the  overseas  Commonwealth.  The 
Commonwealth  countries  received  an  average  of  between  110,000  and 
150,000  emigrants  from  Britain  a  year  and  sent  to  Britain  50,000  or  60,000 
—including  an  unknown  number  of  United  Kingdom  people  who  had 
changed  their  minds  and  returned.28  Australia  absorbed  more  immigrants 
than  any  other  country.  It  is  the  only  Dominion  which,  under  a  joint 
agreement  with  the  United  Kingdom,  shares  with  it  the  entire  cost  of  the 
passage  of  the  immigrant.  It  is  interesting  to  observe  how  the  Dominions, 
in  varying  degrees,  attempt  to  encourage  the  British  migrant.  New  Zea- 
land, for  example,  is  particularly  anxious  not  to  dilute  its  Commonwealth 
blood.  Australia  tries  to  maintain  a  ratio  of  50  per  cent  for  immigrants 
from  Britain,  thus  assuring  a  continuous  predominance  of  United  King- 
dom stock  (which  accounted,  in  1946,  for  over  97  per  cent  of  its  popula- 
tion ) .  The  remaining  Australian  immigrants  include  Italian,  Polish,  Dutch, 
German,  and  displaced  persons.  Canada  displays  much  less  preference  on 
ethnic  grounds  than  do  New  Zealand  and  Australia.  Its  course  has  not 
been  a  determined  Commonwealth  policy.  Out  of  over  a  million  immi- 
grants into  Canada  since  the  end  of  World  War  II,  only  one-third  have 
been  British,  and  yet  the  ties  with  the  Commonwealth  have  not  been 
weakened  by  this  fact.29 

The  countries  receiving  European  immigration  have  generally  profited 
by  this  movement,  if  for  no  other  reason  than  that  they  have  acquired  a 
number  of  skilled  workers  and  entrepreneurs  without  bearing  the  cost  of 
their  education  and  childhood  dependency.  The  economic  problems  of 

28  "People  for  Export,"  The  Economist,  August  28,  1954,  pp.  542  ff. 

29  Ibid. 


376  HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 

assimilation  were  minimized  by  the  high  levels  of  economic  activity  pre- 
vailing in  the  postwar  period.  In  the  underdeveloped  countries,  especially 
of  Latin  America,  even  comparatively  small  numbers  of  European  immi- 
grants are  playing  a  disproportionately  large  role,  since  they  bring  skills, 
work  habits,  and  enterprise  not  commonly  available  in  the  less-developed 
countries.  Only  in  Australia  and  in  Israel  has  immigration  been  so  large  as 
to  create  serious  economic  maladjustments,  notably  in  shortages  of  hous- 
ing and  other  primary  facilities. 

With  the  resolution  of  the  displaced  persons  problem  largely  through 
overseas  migration,  individual  migration  is  again  the  predominant  form. 
Such  migration  is  now  forbidden  by  Eastern  European  countries.  Aside 
from  a  few  intrepid  individuals  who  successfully  escape  through  the  Iron 
Curtain,  Eastern  Europe  is  ceasing  to  be  a  source  of  overseas  migration. 
For  this  reason  potential  migration  to  Israel  from  Europe  has  been  greatly 
reduced.  The  leadership  of  that  country,  which  is  largely  of  European 
origin,  is  concerned  about  cultural  inundation  from  areas  of  new  Jewish 
immigration  (from  Asia  and  Africa)  just  as  are  the  "older"  European 
stocks  in  overseas  countries  with  regard  to  immigrants  of  different  cultural 
background. 

From  the  problem  of  displaced  persons,  interest  in  sponsored  European 
emigration  has  shifted  to  the  problem  of  German  refugees  and  of  popula- 
tion pressure  in  Southern  Europe  and  the  Netherlands.  While  the  German 
refugees  are  far  more  numerous  than  the  displaced  persons  who  were 
handled  by  the  International  Refugee  Organization,  they  have  far  less 
impetus  to  emigrate,  since  they  are  now  resident  in  a  country  of  their  own 
nationality.  Furthermore,  the  rapid  economic  recovery  in  Western  Ger- 
many in  recent  years  is  providing  them  employment  opportunities.  These 
opportunities  may  be  often  less  favorable  than  are  those  for  natives  of 
Western  Germany,  but  more  favorable  than  they  might  expect  to  en- 
counter in  many  overseas  countries. 

Most  of  Western  Europe  has  now  passed  the  demographic  stage  which 
brought  about  the  great  swarming  of  Europeans  overseas  in  the  nine- 
teenth and  early  twentieth  centuries.  Declining  birth  rates  in  the  1930's 
have  so  reduced  the  numbers  entering  the  labor  force  that  pressure  to 
seek  opportunities  abroad  has  been  greatly  reduced.  In  Ireland,  in  Scan- 
dinavia, and  even  in  Germany  there  is  much  less  pressure  to  migrate 
from  demographic  causes  than  there  was  a  generation  ago.  The  lower 
birth  rates  now  prevailing  in  Southern  Europe  indicate  that  pressure  from 
this  source  will  also  shortly  recede  in  that  region,  especially  in  Italy,  where 


MIGRATIONS  377 

the  birth  rate  is  now  quite  low— lower  even  than  in  France,  the  classic- 
country  of  depopulation,  and  much  lower  than  in  the  United  States. 

In  peace,  the  major  continuing  reservoir  of  "normal"  overseas  migration 
in  Western  Europe  is  the  underemployed  rural  populations  of  Southern 
Italy,  Spain,  Portugal,  Greece,  and  to  a  less  extent  the  Netherlands.  This 
reservoir  is  declining,  but  its  need  for  an  outlet  still  poses  one  of  Europe's 
most  pressing  economic  problems.  At  least  for  the  next  ten  years  it  should 
furnish  the  basis  for  continued  overseas  migration,  until  such  time  as 
further  economic  development  on  the  one  hand,  and  demographic  trends 
on  the  other,  may  have  resolved  the  problems  of  population  pressure  in 
these  countries  as  they  have  in  much  of  Northwest  Europe. 

The  great  overseas  migrations  of  Europeans  may  well  be  coming  to  an 
end.  Rising  in  their  place  are  new  pressures  and  new  migrations. 

In  the  United  States  no  frontier  control  has  yet  been  developed  that  is 
tight  enough  to  seal  off  the  two  thousand  miles  of  desert  separating  this 
country  and  Mexico.  In  its  report  to  the  President  the  Commission  on 
Migratory  Labor  in  1952  ruefully  compares  the  total  of  65,000  displaced 
persons  from  Western  Europe  admitted  to  the  United  States  in  1950  with 
the  500,000  "wetbacks"  estimated  to  have  filtered  illegally  across  the  bor- 
der in  that  year. 

Another  interesting  case  in  point,  with  significant  social  and  political 
implications,  is  that  of  Puerto  Rican  mass  emigration  directed  almost  en- 
tirely at  New  York  City.  The  small  island  (3,423  square  miles)  which  is 
plagued  by  a  high  population  density  ( 646  per  square  mile )  of  a  rapidly 
growing  populace  (2,210,000  in  1950,  an  increase  of  18.3  per  cent  over 
1940  30)  has  as  a  Commonwealth  of  the  United  States  the  advantage  that 
it  can  transfer  its  overflow  population  of  United  States  citizens  to  the  con- 
tinental United  States  without  being  hampered  by  immigration  restric- 
tions. As  a  result  the  influx  of  Puerto  Ricans  to  New  York  ( aided  by  the 
low  flight  passage  rates)  has  reached  unforeseen  proportions.  In  1953, 
375,000  Puerto  Ricans  were  listed  in  New  York,  which  figure  reflects  an 
increase  of  54  per  cent  over  the  total  of  246,000  only  three  years  earlier. 
Not  less  than  25  per  cent  of  Puerto  Rico's  total  population  have  left  the 
island  for  the  continent  during  the  last  two  decades.  The  steady  growth 
of  Spanish-speaking  islands  within  the  cosmopolitan  metropolis  of  New 
York  provides  the  city  government  with  major  problems  of  integration  of 
a  large  ethnic  minority  that  is  growing  continuously,  is  endowed  with  the 
privileges  of  citizenship,  and  is  yet  far  from  being  assimilated. 

so  The  Statesman's  Yearbook,  1953,  p.  740. 


M   A    LA    Y    A 


Kuantan:::::::::x:::::4:: 

IT" 


Fig.  10-3.  Chinese  Settlement  in  Malaya:  (1)  predominantly  Chinese;  (2)  strong 

Chinese  minority. 


378 


MIGRATIONS  379 

CHINESE  AND  INDIAN  EMIGRATIONS 

The  primary  interest  of  the  American  and  European  reader  in  overseas 
migration  from  Europe  should  not  detract  from  the  fact  that  immigration 
and  emigration  elsewhere,  particularly  in  certain  Asian  territories,  loom 
large  in  the  political  geography  of  the  countries  concerned.  The  following 
remarks,  far  from  trying  to  exhaust  the  subject,  aim  only  to  call  attention 
to  an  especially  important  area  of  structural  change  due  to  immigration, 
that  of  Chinese  emigration  overseas  toward  the  peninsulas  and  islands  of 
Southeast  Asia. 

Malaya:  A  Case  Study.31  Nowhere  in  the  world  do  we,  in  this  century, 
find  as  complete  a  change  of  the  human  geography  of  a  territory  through 
the  impact  of  immigration  as  in  Malaya  ( Fig.  10-3 ) .  The  following  obser- 
vations on  a  territory  which  is  a  kingpin— economically  and  strategically— 
of  Southeast  Asia,  are  intended  to  illustrate  how  gradual  immigration, 
paralleling  mass  migration,  can  lead  to  a  decisive  reversal  of  the  ethnic 
structure  of  a  country  and,  as  a  result,  to  important  changes  in  its  political 
and  economic  geography. 

Malaya,  an  area  of  slightly  more  than  50,000  square  miles  (somewhat 
smaller  than  Florida),  is  situated  in  the  southern  part  of  the  Malay  Penin- 
sula, an  extension  of  the  southeastern  tip  of  Asia  between  India  and  China. 
A  British  colonial  possession,  it  includes  the  peninsular  mainland  and  the 
island  of  Singapore.  It  has  a  heterogeneous  population  of  some  six  mil- 
lions, composed  of  Malays,  Chinese,  Indians,  and  Europeans.  The  political 
loyalties  of  this  population  as  well  as  their  economic  occupations  which 
differ  greatly  between  its  ethnic  groups,  are  of  no  small  importance.  Two 
vital  commodities— tin,  totaling  more  than  a  quarter  of  the  world's  output, 
and  rubber,  of  which  Malaya  since  World  War  II  has  produced  40  per 
cent  of  the  world's  output,  have  made  the  small  territory  the  single  largest 
earner  of  dollar  exchange  in  the  British  Commonwealth  and  Empire;  the 
naval  and  air  base  of  Singapore  commands  the  narrow  Straits  of  Malacca, 
which  is  the  shortest  connecting  link  between  the  Indian  Ocean  and  the 
South  China  Sea. 

In  this  important  territory  we  find  a  Chinese  community  which,  since 
1941,  has  outnumbered  the  indigenous  Malay  population  ( Chinese  2,615,- 
000,  Malays  2,544,000).  The  rise  of  the  Chinese  group  has  been  rapid  in 
the  last  decades,  for  its  share  of  44.7  per  cent  in  1947  in  the  combined 
area  of  the  Federation  of  Malaya  and  Singapore  (where  the  percentage 

31  F.  H.  Stires,  British  Colonial  Policy  in  Malaya  and  the  Malayan  Chinese  Com- 
munity, 1946-52,  M.A.  thesis,  1953,  Georgetown  University;  T.  E.  Smith,  Population 
Growth  in  Malaya  (London,  1952). 


380  HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 

of  Chinese  is  77.6  per  cent)  compares  with  one  of  35.2  per  cent  in  1921. 
The  majority  of  the  Chinese  population  have  settled  in  the  tin  and  rubber 
producing  regions  along  the  western  coast  of  the  country;  92  per  cent  of 
the  total  present  Chinese  population  is  located  in  the  west  coast  states.32 
Since  1947,  Chinese  immigration  has  been  practically  stopped  by  the 
colonial  administration. 

Ever  since  the  Chinese,  with  British  permission,  migrated  to  Malaya— 
at  first  for  employment  in  the  rubber  plantations  and  in  the  tin  mines— we 
find  the  human,  and  especially  the  economic  and  political  geography  of 
the  country  in  a  state  of  cleavage  and  the  British  colonial  government 
saddled  with  the  most  complicated  tasks  of  balancing  a  radically  changed 
population.  The  gravity  of  these  problems  is  accentuated  by  the  fact  that 
China  has  always  adhered  to  the  principle  of  jus  sanguinis,  according  to 
which  it  viewed  the  overseas  Chinese  as  citizens  of  China,  whose  activi- 
ties, especially  in  the  fields  of  education  and  of  ideological  loyalties, 
should  be  controlled  by  the  homeland  government.33 

One  of  the  main  means  by  which  the  British,  since  1931,  have  attempted 
to  stem  the  Chinese  tide  was  by  the  establishment  of  Malay  Land  Reser- 
vations. The  late  realization  that  the  Malay  people,  as  a  race,  could  not 
compete  with  the  far  more  populous  other  races  attracted  to  Malaya,  led 
to  regulations  under  which  land  from  the  Reservation,  in  particular  land 
suitable  for  rice  cultivation,  could  be  made  available  only  to  Malays.34 

From  whatever  angle  we  view  the  human  and  political  geography  of 
the  Malay  Peninsula,  we  will  trace  the  causes  of  its  radical  changes  in  the 
twentieth  century  and  its  problems  of  co-existence  between  its  ethnic 
groups  to  the  impact  of  immigration,  especially  Chinese  immigration. 

Chinese  Minorities  Overseas.  While  Malaya  is  the  only  countrv  in 
Southeast  Asia  where  the  Chinese  have  become  the  dominant  racial  group, 
the  problems  created  by  Chinese  immigration  are  shared  by  most  other 
Southeast  Asian  countries.  The  total  number  of  Chinese  minorities  is  esti- 
mated at  ten  million.35  Wherever  the  immigrants  went,  they  took  over 

32  In  the  present  Federation  of  Malaya,  which  excludes  the  island  of  Singapore,  the 
Malays  form  the  largest  single  racial  group  (49.5  per  cent),  but  the  combined  Chinese 
(38.4  per  cent)  and  Indians  (10.8  per  cent)  community  is  almost  equally  large  in 
numbers. 

33  V.  Purcell,  The  Chinese  in  Southeast  Asia  (New  York,  1951),  p.  359. 

34  R.  Emerson,  Malaysia,  A  Study  in  Direct  and  Indirect  Rule  (New  York,  1931), 
p.  479.  Additional  problems  have  arisen  since  June  1948  when  an  armed  rebellion 
of  a  Malayan  Communist  Party,  composed  almost  entirely  of  Chinese,  got  under  way. 
The  vast  majority  of  the  Chinese  community  have  remained  aloof  from  this  move- 
ment. For  a  detailed  discussion  see  F.  H.  Stires,  op.  cit.,  pp.  70-82,  and  V.  Thompson 
and  R.  Adloff,  The  Left  Wing  in  Southeast  Asia  (New  York,  1950),  pp.  210-211. 

35  Thailand:   3,000,000   (15.5  per  cent),   in   Bangkok  they  constitute  half  of  the 


MIGRATIONS  381 

control  of  a  disproportionately  large  share  of  the  economy  of  their  new 
country;  they  controlled  the  rice  economy;  they  invaded  successfully  the 
retail,  import  and  export  business,  industry,  and  banking.  Their  ways  of 
life  and  loyalties  toward  their  motherland  left  a  distinctive  mark  on  the 
countries  in  which  they  settled.  Dislocations  caused  by  their  influx 
prompted  a  rewriting  of  the  maps  of  these  countries  to  show  the  social, 
economic,  and  political  factors  as  expressed  in  the  distribution  of  the 
indigenous  and  immigrant  populations.  Malaya  offers,  as  we  have  seen, 
the  most  vivid  illustration.  Politically,  the  fact  that  the  Chinese  Commu- 
nist government  does  not  recognize  the  right  of  any  Chinese  national 
abroad  to  divest  himself  of  Chinese  nationality  accentuates  the  contrast 
between  the  areas  of  Chinese  concentration  overseas  and  those  of  indige- 
nous settlement.36  The  Indian  Prime  Minister  Jawaharlal  Nehru  described 
this  situation  in  1954  as  "frightening." 

Indian  Emigration  Overseas.  Of  similar  nature,  although  not  as  serious 
in  their  power-political  aspects,  are  the  problems  created  by  Indian  emi- 
gration overseas.  For  instance,  Ceylon  has  an  Indian  community  of  about 
900,000,  or  13  per  cent  of  the  island's  population.  In  1954,  negotiations 
between  the  governments  of  India  and  Ceylon  were  under  way  aimed  at 
straightening  out  the  involved  citizenship  problems  of  the  Indian  minority, 
and  at  repatriation  to  India  of  those  who  satisfied  Indian  citizenship  laws. 
According  to  1949  estimates,37  large  communities  of  Indians  are  to  be 
found  in  the  following  countries:  Burma,  700,000;  Malaya,  708,000;  South 
Africa,  282,000;  East  Africa,  184,000;  Mauritius,  271,000  (or  63  per  cent 
of  the  total  population! ) ;  Indonesia,  30,000;  Fiji,  126,000  ( or  46  per  cent 
of  the  total  population);  West  Indies  and  Guianas,  406,000.  In  most  of 
these  areas,  the  influx  and  growth  of  Indian  immigration,  with  its  distinctly 
different  economic,  social,  and  cultural  characteristics,  has  resulted  in 
serious  dislocations  within  the  indigenous  community.  The  strongest  re- 
action took  place  in  South  Africa,  leading  to  appeals  by  the  Indian  popu- 
lation to  its  "homeland"  and  to  the  United  Nations.  The  history  of  South 


population  of  1,000,000;  Indonesia:  2,500,000  (3  per  cent);  Vietnam:  1,000,000 
(5  per  cent);  Cambodia:  300,000  (10  per  cent);  Burma:  300,000  (5  per  cent); 
British  Borneo  and  Sarawak:  220,000  (24.4  per  cent);  Philippines:  120,000  (0.6 
per  cent).  See  also  L.  Unger,  "The  Chinese  in  Southeast  Asia,"  Geographical  Review 
(1944),  pp.  196-217. 

36  For  instance,  the  Indonesian  government  announced  in  October,  1954,  the  de- 
parture of  a  delegation  for  Communist  China  for  the  discussion  of  the  burning 
controversies  over  the  double  citizenship  issue.  Seventy-five  per  cent  of  Indonesia's 
Chinese  minority,  estimated  at  2,000,000  to  3,000,000,  are  Indonesian  citizens,  whose 
allegiance,  however,  is  also  claimed  by  China. 

37  O.  H.  K.  Spate,  op.  cit.,  pp.  112-113. 


382  HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 

African  government  measures  aimed  at  restricting  Indian  immigration 
and  at  limiting  the  freedom  of  movement  and  of  settlement  of  the  Indian 
minority  dates  back  to  1913  when  an  Immigration  Act  restricted  the  immi- 
gration of  Indians  in  appreciable  numbers.  These  measures  paralleled 
those  directed  at  the  segregation  of  the  native  population.  In  addition  to 
its  native  segregation  South  Africa  also  has  a  special  pattern  of  Asian 
(including  Indian,  Goan,  and  Arab)  communities.  Indian  trade  is  confined 
to  certain  areas;  freedom  of  movement  between  the  provinces  is  limited; 
land  tenure  and  occupation  of  land  are  hedged  about  with  legal  restric- 
tions; residential  segregation  is  practiced.  As  citizens,  the  Indians  are 
powerless.  A  report  by  a  study  group  of  the  South  African  Institute  of 
International  Affairs  summed  up  this  situation  in  1951  as  follows:  "In- 
dians in  South  Africa  are,  to  all  intents  and  purposes,  a  voteless  commu- 
nity." 3S  While  discriminatory  measures  by  other  African  governments  do 
not  go  as  far  as  those  in  South  Africa,  the  restrictions  against  the  immigra- 
tion of  "non-natives"  are  widespread:  Kenya,  Uganda,  Tanganyika,  and 
Zanzibar  enacted  such  restrictions  in  1946;  the  Belgians  tended  to  prevent 
Indian  entry  into  the  Congo;  the  Portuguese  restricted  entry  into  Portu- 
guese East  Africa.39 

Such  barriers  frustrate  very  powerful  underlying  forces  for  Asian  demo- 
graphic expansion.  Future  Western  policy-makers  will  have  to  take  into 
account  the  results  of  such  frustrations. 

3 8  Africa  South  of  the  Sahara  (Cape  Town,  1951),  pp.  72-75  (74). 

39  Ibid.,  pp.  73,  74. 


CHAPTER 


11 


The  Political  Geography 
or  Landuades 


A  NOTE  ON  THE  RACIAL  FACTOR  IN 
POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

This  chapter  is  concerned  with  linguistic  factors  as  human  elements  of 
importance  in  the  study  of  political  geography.  Language  is  but  one  of 
several  important  features  of  the  human  element  in  the  cultural  and  politi- 
cal landscape,  the  geographical  distribution  of  which  invites  exploration 
by  the  political  geographer  who  will  focus  his  attention  on  them.  They 
are  features  which  generate  binding  and  separating  forces  in  the  lives  of 
nations.  Religion  and  ethnic  composition  are  other  features  that  must  be 
considered.  But  while  this  book  devotes  a  chapter  to  the  subject  of  the 
political  geography  of  religions,  it  does  not  include  a  detailed  discussion 
of  ethnic  and  racial  factors  as  such.  The  reason  must  be  seen  in  the  fact 
that  it  is  impossible  to  arrive  at  a  satisfactory  classification  of  the  ethnic 
structure  of  states.  There  is  no  state  on  the  world's  map  that  is  not  racially 
heterogeneous.  The  waves  of  mass  migrations,  of  immigration  and  emigra- 
tion, as  well  as  intermarriage  have  "resulted  in  such  a  mixture  of  peoples 
that,  although  ethnologists  suggest  various  broad  groupings  on  the  basis 
of  certain  physical  characteristics,  there  is  no  possibility  of  defining  these 
groups  by  acceptable  linear  boundaries."  1 

On  the  other  hand,  we  must  be  cognizant  of  one  broad  racial  divide 

1  A.  E.  Moodie,  Geography  Behind  Politics  (London,  1947),  p.  51;  see  also  A.  C. 
Haddon,  The  Races  of  Man  (London,  1929),  pp.  139  flE. 

383 


384  HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 

between  the  world  of  the  "white  man"  and  that  of  the  non-white  races. 
The  contours  of  this  ominous  dividing  line  are  as  hazy  as  ever,  but  at  the 
time  these  lines  are  written  they  are  deepening  and  the  boundary  between 
the  two  is  about  to  assume  a  new  meaning  in  international  relations.  In 
April,  1955,  a  conference  of  twenty-nine  Afro-Asian  nations  was  held  in 
Bandung,  Indonesia,  which  included  the  widest  possible  variety  of  coun- 
tries extending  from  Libya  to  Japan  and  encompassing  more  than  half  of 
the  world's  population.  In  spite  of  numerous  separating  factors  in  the 
realms  of  religion,  language,  and  race,  of  political  philosophies  and  affilia- 
tions, of  cultural  and  economic  systems,  the  nations  assembled  in  Bandung 
had  in  common  that  they  were,  in  a  crude,  general  way,  non-white  and 
that  they  were  suspicious  of  the  white  man's  world,  due  to  their  common 
heritage  of  having  been  at  one  time  or  another  under  the  control  of  white 
colonial  powers.  Such  a  division  between  the  two  worlds  of  white  and 
non-white  people  signifies  the  importance  of  this  broad  racial  distinction 
in  the  political  geography  of  today. 

LANGUAGE  AS  A  MAJOR  FACTOR  OF  UNIFICATION  AND 
DIVISION  IN  THE  LIVES  OF  NATIONS 

The  French  Academy,  about  fifteen  years  ago,  drew  from  numerous 
studies  in  the  field  of  linguistics  the  conclusion  that  the  number  of  lan- 
guages still  alive  on  this  globe  is  2,796.  The  Tower  of  Babel  is  still  a 
reality.  As  the  biblical  story  may  be  an  echo  of  the  problems  once  vexing 
ancient  tyrants  whose  realms  embraced  countries  of  many  languages  and 
dialects,  so  language  today  is  a  vital  factor  in  the  division  or  unification 
of  nations.  In  the  creation  and  preservation  of  national  consciousness, 
language  has  played  a  major  role.  Each  nation  strives  to  have  a  language 
of  its  own,  a  common  language  which  forms  the  strongest  unifying  symbol 
in  the  life  of  a  national  community.  This  desire  has  often  given  rise  to  a 
national  or  regional  consciousness  so  intense  as  to  lead  to  separatist  move- 
ments.2 Agitations  for  the  Breton  and  Catalan  languages  have  disturbed 
the  political  equilibrium  of  France  and  Spain;  in  Eire,  an  intensified  na- 
tionalism has  given  rise  to  a  determined  effort  to  revive  the  Irish  language; 
in  the  Ukraine,  one  of  the  major  obstacles  to  the  efforts  of  the  Kremlin  in 
integrating  this  country  into  the  U.S.S.R.  has  been  the  determined  unwill- 
ingness of  the  Ukrainian  peasantry  to  give  up  the  Ukrainian  language  for 
Russian;  in  South  Tyrol,  the  attempts  by  the  Fascist  Italian  regime  to  im- 
pose the  Italian  language   on  the   German-speaking  population   failed 

2  L.  H.  Gray,  Foundations  of  Language  (New  York,  1939),  p.  117. 


THE  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY  OF  LANGUAGES  385 

because  of  the  determination  of  the  mountain  people  to  preserve  their 
language. 

On  the  other  hand,  there  are  examples  of  nations  which  are  unified 
without  a  language  peculiar  to  themselves,  and  each  without  a  language 
spoken  by  all  the  people.  Switzerland  is  a  nation  with  a  strong  and  healthy 
national  consciousness,  and  yet  it  is  inhabited  by  speakers  of  German, 
French,  Italian,  and  Rhaeto-Romanic,  all  four  recognized  as  of  equal 
standing.  Relgium  is  another  example  of  a  nation  linguistically  divided, 
in  this  case  between  French  and  Flemish,  although  its  unity,  especially 
since  World  War  II,  has  had  to  weather  many  a  storm.  Then  again,  we 
observe  nations  co-existing  peacefully,  but  not  united,  in  the  face  of  the 
fact  that  they  are  linguistically  almost  identical,  such  as  Denmark  and 
Norway.  Dano-Norwegian  has  been  the  literary  language  of  Norway.  But 
the  Danes  and  Norwegians  do  not  regard  that  fact  as  any  reason  for  merg- 
ing the  two  nations  into  one.  Or,  as  one  British  student  of  linguistics  re- 
marked (and  obviously  with  his  tongue  in  his  cheek),  "English  is  the 
language  of  the  United  States  of  America.  That  is  no  reason  for  the  United 
States  to  annex  the  British  Empire."  3 

THE  CASE  OF  INDIA  AND  PAKISTAN 

The  above  examples  were  chosen  at  random  to  emphasize  the  great 
importance  of  the  element  of  language  in  the  internal  and  external  politics 
of  nations.  Before  we  look  more  closely  at  the  relationship  of  language 
and  linguistic  boundaries  to  political  geography,  one  further  example  will 
illustrate  the  powerful  influence  the  language  factor  still  exerts  in  the 
destinies  of  nations,  leading  in  this  instance  to  a  redrawing  of  the  political 
map  (Fig.  11-1).  In  India,  in  1953,  the  new  state  of  Andhra  was  inaugu- 
rated. This  was  the  first  step  toward  a  complete  remodeling  of  the  internal 
political  geography  of  the  subcontinent.  Of  India's  450  million  inhabitants, 
at  least  250  million  speak  Indo-Iranian  languages,  while  about  100  million 
use  Dravidian  tongues.4  Actually,  the  picture  is  much  more  complicated: 
Hindi,  the  national  language  of  India  under  the  Constitution,  is  spoken  by 
42  per  cent  of  the  population.  According  to  the  government's  program  it  is 
to  be  adopted  as  the  official  language  by  1956.  Besides  this,  15  major 
languages  are  recognized  by  the  Constitution,  as  well  as  720  dialects, 
24  distinct  but  minor  languages,  and  23  tribal  tongues.5  Geographically, 

3  A.  C.  Woolner,  Languages  in  History  and  Politics  (London,  1938),  p.  10. 

4  M.  Pei,  The  Story  of  Language  (New  York,  1949),  p.  353. 

5  These  figures  are  based  on  an  Indian  census  published  in  April,  1954;  New  York 
Times,  April  10,  1954.  See  also  O.  H.  K.  Spate,  India  and  Pakistan,  p.  125,  who  points 
out  that  in  1931,  six  languages  accounted  for  65  per  cent  of  the  population. 


AFGHANISTAN  ( 


VS 


•"v 


s-   / 


,".s^,r" 


• 


•>* 


../ 


••  KASHMIR 

AND 
JAMMU  ^ 


j 


^^^^     CHfNA 


W® 


\ 


/ 


\ 

i 


v 


t 


( 

i    PUNJAB      / 

PAKISTAN         J*  V  (  /  ^-x  *  / 

V\  ^-•*  V  ^  /  v»  _*  \    Je  wvTAN  •     .Jl...'  .' 

—      \f-sSi  ASSAM      y./ 


..^..< 


Fig.  11-1.  Linguistic  States  of  India:  (1)  Gujerat;  (2)  Maharahshtra;  (3)  Andhra; 
(4)  Kanrataka;  (5)  Kerala  ( after  The  Economist ) . 


386 


THE  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY  OF  LANGUAGES  387 

the  Dravidian  languages  are  those  of  India's  south,  while  the  Indo-Iranian 
languages  are  spoken  in  the  north.  Between  these  two  major  competing 
linguistic  groups  lingers  the  official  language  of  the  recent  past,  English, 
which  the  Indian  government  is  obligated  to  abolish  within  the  next  fif- 
teen years.  In  a  way,  the  language  problems  and  cleavages  which  threaten 
the  unity  of  the  new  state  of  India  and  divide  its  people  in  the  north  and 
south  can  be  compared  with  the  conflict  which,  a  hundred  years  earlier, 
threatened  the  unity  of  the  young  United  States. 

What  happened  in  India  on  October  1,  1953,  when  the  separate  state 
to  be  known  as  Andhra  was  formed  for  20  million  Telugu  speakers  of 
Madras,  represents  the  surrender  of  India's  central  government  to  the 
demand  that  the  country  should  redraw  its  internal  boundaries  to  give  a 
dozen  major  linguistic  groups  states  of  their  own.  The  principle  itself  is 
not  quite  new  in  India.  Even  before  1914,  when  the  British  created  Assam 
and  Bihar  out  of  Bengal,  and  the  North-West  Frontier  Province  of  the 
Punjab,  the  new  creations  were  largely,  but  not  entirely,  linguistic.6  After 
independence  was  won  by  India,  after  the  battle  cry  for  linguistic  states 
was  no  longer  a  demand  by  the  Congress  Party  to  the  Colonial  Govern- 
ment but  a  problem  of  the  new  Indian  nation  itself,  it  became  evident  to 
its  leaders  that  overemphasis  on  linguistic  factors  in  the  redrawing  of  the 
political  geography  of  the  country  threatened  to  foster  a  new  concept  of 
belonging  together  and  of  nationalism  based  on  language,  and  that  this 
strong  unifying  bond  militated  against  a  wider  loyalty  to  India  as  a  whole. 
It  was  feared  that  controversies  over  the  new  boundaries  might  upset 
national  unity  and  divert  the  people's  efforts  from  the  more  urgent  eco- 
nomic and  political  problems.  Yet  the  force  of  the  popular  demand  for 
recognition  of  the  language  principle  as  a  basis  for  a  system  of  new  Indian 
states  had  become  so  vehement  that  the  wind  which  the  Congress  Party 
once  sowed  now  turned  into  a  tempest.  Thus  Andhra  was  born  and  a  new 
map  of  India  based  on  linguistic  principles  is  taking  shape. 

In  the  fall  of  1955,  Prime  Minister  Nehru  presented  a  reorganization 
plan  for  redrawing  completely  the  political  map  of  the  federal  republic  of 
India.  While  its  states  are  as  administrative  bodies  less  powerful  than  are 
the  states  in  the  United  States,  the  cultural  and  linguistic  differences  and 
cleavages  are  much  more  formidable.  Under  the  new  plan,  in  place  of  the 
present  twenty-nine  states  ( in  contrast  to  the  quilt  of  seventeen  provinces 
and  about  six  hundred  princely  states  at  the  time  when  independence  was 
won  by  India)  there  would  be  only  sixteen.  Only  two  of  them,  Bombay 
and  the  Punjab,  will  be  bilingual.  Four  of  the  large  states  will  be  Hindi 

6  "Linguistic  States  in  India,"  The  Economist,  October  3,  1953. 


388  HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 

speaking  units,  and  Hindi  is  to  be  the  national  language.  History  will  tell 
whether  this  scheme  will  succeed  in  overcoming  the  strong  forces  of  re- 
gionalism and  separatism  at  work  throughout  India.  The  strength  of  these 
forces  is  indicated  by  the  fact  that  the  Indian  Congress  Working  Commit- 
tee shortly  after  the  new  plan  was  presented  gave  in  to  the  demands  of 
the  Marahashtrians  of  central  and  western  India,  who  agitate  for  a  sepa- 
rate Marathi-speaking  state  of  their  own,  and  decided  to  split  up  the 
present  state  of  Bombay  to  form  three  states.7 

In  Pakistan,  where  many  economic,  ethnic,  religious,  and  cultural  fac- 
tors threaten  the  uneasy  balance  between  its  eastern  and  western  parts, 
problems  having  their  origin  in  Pakistan's  complicated  geography  of  lan- 
guages have  become  increasingly  serious.  The  Moslem  League  govern- 
ment in  Karachi  tried  to  decree  that  Urdu  ( the  Hindustani  variant  spoken 
by  Moslems)  be  used  as  official  language  in  both  Pakistans.  But  eastern 
Pakistan  is  linguistically  and  culturally  part  of  Bengal.  The  speakers  of 
the  Bengali  tongue,  who  number  sixty  million,  are  more  numerous  than 
any  language  group  in  western  Pakistan  and  their  opposition  against  the 
attempt  to  force  upon  them  an  alien  official  language  was  violent.  In  May, 
1954,  they  succeeded  in  transforming  Pakistan  into  a  multilingual  state. 
Pakistan's  assembly  accepted  a  resolution  declaring  that  Urdu  and  Ben- 
gali should  be  official  languages,  and  in  addition  "such  other  provincial 
languages  as  may  be  declared  to  be  such  by  the  Head  of  the  State  on 
recommendation  of  the  provincial  legislatures."  8  English  will  be  allowed 
to  function  as  lingua  franca  until  1967.9 

LANGUAGE  AS  BINDING  ELEMENT 

The  India  and  Pakistan  examples  offer  in  a  nutshell  a  picture  of  the 
multitude  of  significant  problems  with  which  the  geography  of  languages 
confronts  the  student  of  political  geography.  We  shall  now  try  to  define 
some  of  these  problems. 

There  are  many  factors  which  contribute  to  binding  communities  and 
populations  together.  One,  if  not  the  strongest  element  in  the  process  of 
cementing  a  nation  is  the  possession  of  a  common  language.  Bace  ( actual 

7  A.  M.  Rosenthal,  New  York  Times,  October  23,  1955;  ibid,  October  10,  1955  and 
November  13,  1955. 

8  Pei,  op.  cit.,  pp.  286,  346;  W.  G.  East  and  O.  H.  K.  Spate,  The  Changing  Map 
of  Asia  (London,  1950),  p.  123;  and  Neue  Zurcher  Zeitung,  March  25,  1954,  p.  1; 
New  York  Times,  March  8,  1954,  p.  5. 

9  The  discussion  of  language  factors  in  the  Indian  Union  and  Pakistan  is  not  meant 
to  detract  from  the  fact  that  the  principal  cleavage  in  India  is  one  of  religion. 


THE  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY  OF  LANGUAGES  389 

blood-affinity  and,  even  more  potent,  the  imagined  racial  community 
preached  by  the  drummers  of  political  pseudo-philosophies),  ethno- 
graphic factors,  the  unifying  force  of  religion,  and  the  manifold  elements 
of  a  common  history  and  traditions— all  work  together  in  the  process  of 
amalgamation  which  creates  and  continuously  recreates  the  substance  of 
a  nation.  But  language  is  always  an  essential  factor,  sometimes  competing 
with  religion  in  the  order  of  importance.10  A  common  language  must  al- 
ways be  considered  a  powerful  bond,  uniting  a  people  within  a  commu- 
nity of  ideas  and  ideals.  Switzerland,  with  its  four  official  languages,  is  not 
an  exception  but  rather  emphasizes  the  fact  that  the  mosaic  of  each 
nation  is  so  complex,  the  mosaic  stones  so  different  in  appearance,  that 
we  cannot  expect  to  find  a  general  formula  composed  of  linguistic,  racial, 
and  physical  factors  from  which  the  definition  of  a  nation  or  nationality 
can  be  derived. 


THE  LINGUISTIC  FACTOR  AS  A  RARRIER 

Just  as  a  common  language  cements  and  binds  and  creates  a  strong 
feeling  of  belonging-together,  the  lack  of  a  common  language  will  form 
a  barrier  between  peoples,  unless,  as  in  Switzerland,  common  memories 
prove  strong  enough  to  challenge  the  factors  of  disunity  and  isolation 
which  differences  in  language  are  apt  to  create.11  In  India,  as  discussed 
above,  we  have  an  illustration  of  the  conflicting  powers  at  work.  It  is  still 
too  early  to  say  whether  the  unifying  elements  upon  which  the  Indian 
government  rests  its  claim  for  national  unity  will  develop  sufficient 
strength  to  offset  the  separating  factors  based  on  linguistic  differences. 

The  problems  with  which  India  and  Pakistan  are  at  present  confronted 
within  their  national  boundaries  illustrate  another  important  factor:  dif- 
ferences in  language  are  not  only  barriers  between  nation  and  nation. 
Where  more  than  one  language  is  spoken  within  the  national  boundaries 
of  a  nation— even  where  different  dialects  prevail— the  germ  of  not-belong- 
ing-together exists  and  serious  problems  affecting  in  many  ways  the  inter- 
nal geography  of  a  nation  are  apt  to  arise.  There  is  scarcely  a  nation  on 

10  India  offers  a  good  illustration  in  confirmation  of  this  statement.  To  quote 
O.  H.  K.  Spate  (Geography  of  India  and  Pakistan,  p.  125):  "The  'racial'  element  has 
indeed  its  importance— a  very  great  importance— in  the  cultural  history  of  India;  it  is 
of  little  practical  significance  today.  Few  Indians  ( and  for  that  matter  few  English- 
men) could  speak  with  any  degree  of  scientific  accuracy  as  to  their  racial  origins; 
everyone  knows  what  language  he  speaks.  Next  to  religion  language  is  the  greatest 
divisive  force  in  India  ( and  Pakistan )  today." 

11  M.  Huber,  "Swiss  Nationality,"  in  A.  Zimmern,  ed.,  Modern  Political  Doctrines 
(London,  1939),  pp.  216-217. 


390  HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 

the  political  map  of  the  world  without  dividing  factors  which  have  their 
origin  in  linguistic  differences.  In  each  case,  the  nature  of  the  problems 
arising  from  such  differences  has  characteristics  of  its  own  and  is,  above 
all,  determined  by  the  relationship  between,  and  the  relative  power  of, 
the  various  language  groups  brought  together  under  one  nation's  sover- 
eignty. Rarely  do  we  find  cultural  and  political  equality  between  language 
groups  such  as  it  exists  in  Switzerland.  Mostly  the  co-existence  between 
majority  and  minority  groups,  between  conqueror  and  conquered,  be- 
tween colonial  power  and  indigenous  population,  will  accentuate  the  in- 
ternal problems.  Thus  the  language  map  which  distinguishes  between 
linguistic  groups  within  a  nation's  boundaries— by  showing  the  islands  and 
pockets  of  discernible  language,  or  on  a  somewhat  different  plane,  dialect 
—cannot  possibly  do  justice  to  the  many  distinctions  which,  nationwide, 
characterize  the  relations  of  language  groups  and  thus  form  an  integral 
and  important  part  of  a  country's  cultural  and  political  geography. 

REGIONAL  CASE  STUDIES 

Canada.  The  internal  political  geography  of  Canada  is  distinguished  by 
the  relationship  between  its  English  element  and  the  vigorous  French 
group,  representing  more  than  four-fifths  ( about  4,000,000 )  of  the  popu- 
lation of  Quebec,  or  one-third  of  Canada's  total  population  of  15,000,000  12 
(Fig.  11-2).  De  Tocqueville's  prophecy  of  1830  that  the  French  were  "the 
wreck  of  an  old  people  lost  in  the  flood  of  a  new  nation,"  13  was  disproved 
by  history.  A  comparison  of  Ontario  and  Quebec  shows  striking  differences 
in  their  respective  human  and  social  geographies.  There  has  been  no  melt- 
ing pot.  The  French  Canadians  like  to  think  of  themselves  as  les  Cano- 
diens,  and  of  the  rest  of  their  compatriots  as  les  Anglais.  In  addition  to 
cultural  and  linguistic  and,  above  all,  religious  factors,  geography  has 
played  a  leading  part  in  keeping  the  two  nationalities  alive  under  the  same 
Canadian  flag  and  preventing  them  from  getting  "lost  in  the  flood  of  a  new 
nation":  set  off  by  themselves,  surrounded  on  three  sides  by  the  Gulf  of  St. 
Lawrence  and  the  forested  highlands  to  the  north  and  south,  the  French 
Canadians  are  approaching  their  third  century  of  agricultural  and  social 
isolation,  with  strong  Anglo-French  demarcations  highlighted  by  linguistic 
divides.14 

12  Official  Canadian  statistics  for  1954  show  that  despite  occasional  sharp  differ- 
ences between  the  French  Canadian  groups  and  the  majority  groups  of  English- 
speaking  Canadians  in  immigration,  births,  infant  mortality,  and  marriages,  the 
proportion  remains  the  same, 

13  J.  R.  Smith  and  M.  O.  Phillips,  North  America,  2nd  ed.  (New  York,  1942),  p.  72. 

14  Ibid.,  pp.  631-639. 


THE  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY  OF  LANGUAGES 


391 


^ T^ 


r 


%>J\  7 


"•*.      / 


.L_l  .* 


\m~am — >■» 


Fig.  11-2.  Canada:  "Les  Canadiens":  (1)  English  language  area;  (2)  French 

language  area. 

Union  of  South  Africa.  In  comparison  and  contrast,  the  geography  of 
languages  in  the  Union  of  South  Africa  reveals  the  two  competing  white 
groups,  the  Boers  and  the  English,  in  an  altogether  different  environmen- 
tal setting.  While  it  is  true  in  the  case  of  two  language  groups  in  Canada, 
and  in  the  case  of  four  language  groups  in  Switzerland,  that  a  more  or  less 
accurate  linguistic  borderline  separates  one  linguistic  group  from  the 
other,  the  geography  of  languages,  with  its  political  implications,  is  much 
more  complex  in  South  Africa.  There  is  no  clearly  defined  linguistic 
boundary  line.  In  answer  to  the  question  put  to  the  white  population  in 
the  1946  census  as  to  which  language  they  spoke  at  home,  57.3  per  cent 
stated  Afrikaans  (language  of  the  Boers)  and  39.4  per  cent  English;  1.3 
per  cent  declared  themselves  bilingual.  In  broad  terms,  one  can  observe 
Boer  and  British  preponderance  region-wise,  with  the  British  in  the  ma- 
jority along  the  coast,  in  the  Cape  Province  and,  above  all,  in  Natal,  and 
the  Boers  having  their  strongest  positions  in  the  interior,  in  Transvaal,  and 
especially  in  the  Orange  Free  State.  More  significant  than  the  regional 
divide  is  that  between  town  and  country.  On  a  town-country  level,  the 
rural  districts,  with  an  Afrikaans-speaking  majority  of  82.4  per  cent,  dis- 
play clearly  the  strength  of  the  Boer  element  among  the  white  farming 
population.  In  the  cities,  the  ratio  of  48.5  per  cent  English  to  47.8  per  cent 
Afrikaans  reveals  here  the  major  zones  of  competition  and  conflict,  com- 
plicated by  the  fact  that  English  is  a  world  language  and  Afrikaans  a 
provincial  tongue.15 

15  R.  P.  Hafter,  "British  and  Boers  in  South  Africa,"  Neue  Ziircher  Zeitung,  June  5, 
1954.    In   this   competition   between   English-    and    Afrikaans-speaking   whites,    time 


392  HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 

Yugoslavia.  Yugoslavia  offers  an  interesting  example  of  a  country  which, 
during  the  short  span  of  its  history,  has  astonishingly  well  succeeded  in 
binding  together  a  great  variety  of  ethnic,  linguistic,  and  religious 
groups,16  in  the  past  torn  apart  by  bitter  feuds.  Its  total  area  of  about 
97,000  square  miles  ( one-half  the  size  of  France  or  Spain,  about  the  same 
size  as  Wyoming  or  Oregon)  harbored  in  1954  a  population  of  seventeen 
million.  Its  main  nationalities,  comprising  87.4  per  cent  of  the  population, 
are  the  Slovenes,  Croats,  Serbs,  and  Macedonians.17  They  are  set  apart 
by  three  major  languages:  Serbo-Croat,  Slovene,  and  Macedonian.18  The 
dividing  lines  are  even  more  accentuated  by  the  fact  that  the  Yugoslavs 
adopted  two  alphabets,  each  associated  with  one  of  the  major  religions. 
The  Slovenes  and  Croats,  largely  Roman  Catholic,  use  the  Latin  alphabet, 
whereas  the  Serbs  and  Macedonians,  largely  Serb  Orthodox,  use  the  Cyril- 
lic alphabet,  a  modified  form  of  the  Greek  alphabet.19  The  close  link 
between  linguistic  and  religious  elements  in  Yugoslavia  illustrates  the 
blending  of  ethnic,  linguistic,  and  religious  factors  which  co-operate  to 
distinguish  groups  within  a  multination  state.  Such  a  blending  contributes 
to  strengthening  the  contours  of  boundary  lines  within  the  state  and  de- 
picting its  internal  cultural  and  political  geography. 


seems  to  be  on  the  side  of  the  latter.  School  statistics  for  1954,  as  reported  in  the 
Neio  York  Times  of  January  24,  1954,  show  that  there  are  twice  as  many  Afrikaans- 
speaking  white  children  in  the  public  schools  as  English-speaking  children  ( and  that 
African  Negro  children  far  outnumber  both).  It  is  safe  to  predict  that  the  English- 
speaking  whites  in  most  of  South  Africa  are  on  the  way  to  becoming  a  minority  in 
the  next  generation;  only  the  Natal  coastal  province  and  the  adjacent  northeastern 
corner  of  Cape  Province  are  likely  to  remain  as  areas  of  English-language  pre- 
dominance. 

16  See  pp.  431,  432,  435,  436. 

17  It  should  be  noted  that  in  addition  to  its  contrasting  majority  groups  Yugo- 
slavia has  also  a  highly  complex  minorities  situation:  Albanians,  somewhat  less  than 
800,000,  comprise  about  5  per  cent  of  the  country's  total  population.  A  look  at  the 
map  reveals  the  precarious  border  situation  between  Albania  and  Yugoslavia.  Since 
the  bulk  of  the  Albanian  minority  is  to  be  found  in  the  Kosmet  border  region,  this 
fact  emphasizes  the  problems  arising  out  of  the  existence  of  so  considerable  a 
minority  group  close  to  the  boundary  of  the  Soviet  satellite  Albania.  Other  minorities 
include  Hungarians  (500,000),  Rumanians,  Czechoslovaks,  Turks,  and  Italians.  The 
above  information  is  based  on  U.S.  Department  of  Commerce,  Bureau  of  the  Census, 
The  Population  of  Yugoslavia  (Washington,  D.  C,  1954),  pp.  52-55. 

18  For  centuries,  Macedonia  has  been  a  cradle  of  conflict  between  the  nations 
represented  today  by  Bulgaria,  Yugoslavia,  Greece,  and  Albania.  It  is  of  interest  to 
note  that  the  most  recent  attempt  to  solve  the  Macedonian  problem  has  been  under- 
taken on  a  linguistic  basis.  Macedonia  is  one  of  Yugoslavia's  six  autonomous  republics. 
Of  its  population  of  about  1,200,000,  some  800,000  are  classified  as  "Macedonians," 
and  strong  efforts  are  made  by  the  Belgrade  government  to  solidify  this  ethnic  group 
through  the  development  of  a  Macedonian  language  and  a  folk  culture  of  its  own. 
For  details,  see  H.  R.  Wilkinson,  Maps  and  Politics,  A  Review  of  the  Ethnographic 
Cartography  of  Macedonia  (Liverpool,  1951),  p.  165. 

19  Ibid.,  pp.  14-15. 


THE  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY  OF  LANGUAGES  393 

SUMMARY 

In  spite  of  many  differences,  we  can  describe  Canada  and  Switzerland, 
or  Belgium  and  the  United  Kingdom,  and  even  Yugoslavia,  as  countries 
in  which  the  various  linguistic  groups  harmoniously— in  spite  of  occasional 
friction— collaborate  and  respect  each  other.  In  contrast,  in  the  South 
African  Union,  its  colonial  background,  the  memories  of  the  Boer  War, 
and  the  violent  controversy  over  the  Apartheid  policy  of  the  government 
prompt  many  among  the  Boer  extremists  to  look  upon  their  English- 
speaking  countrymen  as  intruders  and  invaders. 

LINGUISTIC  ISLANDS  AS  ZONES  OF  FRICTION 

Europe.  This  leads  us  to  those  political  areas  in  which  linguistic  minori- 
ties, as  in  the  case  of  the  Germans  in  pre- World  War  II  Poland  and  Czech- 
oslovakia, remain  an  alien  substance  within  the  body  politic.  In  these 
areas,  the  explosive  conflicts  caused  by  hostile  linguistic  groups  led  to 
radical  solution  of  the  problem  by  mass  expulsions  of  eight  million  so- 
called  ethnic  Germans  (whose  distinguishing  characteristic  was  the  lan- 
guage factor)  from  East  European  countries.  Often  the  problems  resulting 
from  the  existence  of  "foreign"  language  groups  within  the  boundaries  of 
a  nation  are  critically  increased  by  the  location  of  such  linguistic  islands 
near  or  along  a  border,  thus  bringing  the  language  (or  ethnic)  minority 
close  to  a  neighbor  with  whom  this  minority  shares  not  only  a  common 
language  but  other  tangible  and  intangible  interests  as  well.  Most  of  the 
boundary  problems  which  vex  the  nations  of  Europe  at  this  time  are  only 
to  a  small  degree  caused  by  differences  over  factors  concerning  the  physi- 
cal geography  of  the  frontier  zone;  they  arise,  rather,  as  factors  of  human 
geography,  among  which  the  problems  of  conflicting  linguistic  and  politi- 
cal boundaries  loom  large.  This  is  true  in  the  following  active  and  dormant 
boundary  disputes  along  the  frontiers  of  Europe;  the  map  of  Europe 
which  shows  these  zones  of  friction  over  linguistic  and  political  bound- 
aries illustrates  how  language  plays  a  paramount  role  among  the  factors 
which  account  for  the  unstable  political  frontiers  of  Europe.20 

In  connection  with  the  discussion  of  "dormant"  disputes  in  Europe,  in 
border  regions  where  an  ethnic  minority  is  geographically  close  to  the 
"motherland,"  mention  should  be  made  of  the  highly  involved  case  of  Ire- 
land, where  more  English  is  at  present  spoken  than  Irish  (which  belongs 

20  List  from  G.  W.  Hoffman,  "Boundary  Problems  in  Europe,"  Annals  of  the  As- 
sociation of  American  Geographers  (1954),  p.  107. 


394 


HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 


to  the  Celtic  group  of  Indo-European  languages)  by  its  three  million 
people.  To  Irish  nationalism  the  partition  of  Ireland  will  always  appear 
intolerable,  and  Eire  has  never  recognized  the  separation  of  the  six  North- 
ern Counties.  The  language  factor  here  is  of  minor  importance  because  of 
the  dominant  position  of  the  English  language,  especially  in  the  North. 
Ireland  is  a  good  illustration  of  the  importance  of  the  religious  factor  in 
political  geography:  the  Southern  population  is  94  per  cent  Catholic,  the 
Northern  66  per  cent  non-Catholic.  In  a  reunited  Ireland  the  non-Catho- 
lics would  amount  to  a  little  less  than  25  per  cent.21  In  all  its  complexity, 
the  Irish  problem  shows  the  linguistic  factor  as  only  one  element,  and  in 
this  case  not  a  decisive  one,  molding  the  human  geography  of  the  country. 

TABLE  11-1 


POPULATION 

SPEAK 

NOW 

LANGUAGE 

CONTROLLED 

CLAIMED 

TOTAL            OF  CLAIMANT 

DISPUTED  AREA 

BY 

BY 

(000s) 

—PER  CENT 

A.  Active  Disputes 

Dutch-German 

Netherlands 

Germany 

9.5 

100 

Saar 

r  Semi-inde- 
<  pendent 
I  France 

Germany 

943. 

100 

South  Tyrol 

Italy 

Austria 

340 

60 

B.  Dormant  Disputes 

N.  Epirus 

Albania 

Greece 

320 

20 

E.  Germany 

(  Poland 
{  U.S.S.R. 

W.  Germany 

6,000  (close 

to)  100 

Karelia-Viipuri 

U.S.S.R. 

Finland 

400 

? 

Slovenia  (Yugoslavia) 
Carinthia  (Austria) 

Austria 

Yugoslavia 

190 

30 

Linguistic  Divides  in  Asian  Frontier  Zones.  In  the  frontier  zones  of 
Asia,  where  nomadic  people  flow  back  and  forth  across  the  borders,  the 
linguistic  divides  differ  in  character  from  those  in  the  borderlands  settled 
by  the  sedentary  people  of  Europe.  But  here,  too,  we  can  observe  the 
centripetal  force  of  linguistic  kinship  which  tends  to  consolidate  people 
separated  by  political  boundaries.  An  example  is  provided  by  the 
Soviet-supported  efforts  of  Afghanistan  to  sponsor  a  Pathan  nation 
— Pushtunistan— which  would  unite  about  seven  million  Pathan  tribesmen 
now  living  in  disputed  areas  of  Pakistan  in  a  state  which  would  be  domi- 

21  J.  V.  Kelleher,  "Can  Ireland  Unite?",  The  Atlantic  Monthly  (April,  1954),  pp. 
58-62;  I.  Bowman,  The  New  World  (New  York,  1921),  pp.  30-35. 


THE  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY  OF  LANGUAGES  395 

nated  by  the  Afghanistan  government  and  would  extend  that  country's 
control  over  western  Pakistan  from  the  Hindu  Kush  range  in  the  north 
to  the  Arabian  seacoast  of  Baluchistan  in  the  south.  Sinkiang  serves  as 
another  illustration.  Here,  too,  the  frontier  between  China  and  the 
U.S.S.R.  is  not  a  line  but  a  zone.  "Except  for  the  Amur  and  Ussuri  frontiers 
between  the  Northeastern  Provinces  and  Siberia,  the  entire  land  frontier 
could  be  arbitrarily  shifted  either  several  hundred  miles  to  the  north  or 
several  hundred  miles  to  the  south  and  still  affect  practically  no  Russians 
and  practically  no  Chinese."  22  Ethnically  and  linguistically,  the  frontier 
zone  is  interwoven  and  penetrated  in  both  directions  by  Kazakh,  Uiqur, 
and  Kirghiz  groups  and  linguistic  patterns.23 

STABILITY  AND  INSTABILITY  OF  BOUNDARIES  AND 
THE  LANGUAGE  FACTOR 

If  one  focuses  attention  on  those  sensitive  spots  along  a  political  bound- 
ary where  the  linguistic  and  the  political  boundary  fall  apart,  one  has  to 
distinguish  between  the  political  boundary  which,  in  spite  of  lacking 
identity  with  the  language  boundary,  has  demonstrated  stability  in  its 
history,  and  the  political  boundary  which,  cutting  across  a  cultural  land- 
scape whose  populace  speaks  the  same  language  and  shares  the  same 
traditions  and  memories  of  a  common  history,  still  has  to  pass  the  test  of 
time.  Typical  of  the  first  is  the  boundary  separating  Germany  and  Switzer- 
land. The  other  extreme  is  exemplified  by  the  temporary  political  bound- 
ary which  follows  the  Iron  Curtain  and  cuts  a  Germany  which  is  practi- 
cally without  linguistic  or  ethnic  minorities  into  two  political  units— West 
Germany,  and  the  "German  Democratic  Republic"  in  what  was,  until  1954, 
the  Soviet  Zone  of  Occupation.  Even  though  the  future  of  Germany  and 
its  frontier  is  still  in  balance,  this  example  shows  clearly  the  fallacy  of 
drawing  a  boundary  that  disregards  completely  the  intangible  factors  of 
belonging-together  that  cement  a  nation.  Such  intangibles  account  for  the 
unity  which  the  United  States  achieved  and  has  maintained  in  spite  of  the 
many  separating  factors  which  brought  about  the  Civil  War. 

22  O.  Lattimore,  "The  Inland  Crossroads  of  Asia,"  in  H.  W.  Weigert  and  V. 
Stefansson,  eds.,  Compass  of  the  World   (New  York,  1949),  pp.  374-394   (386). 

23  O.  Caroe,  "Soviet  Empire,"  in  The  Turks  of  Central  Asia  and  Stalinism  (London, 
1953),  map  after  p.  272;  see  also  pp.  32-34,  43,  255. 


396  HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 

IRREDENTISM 

The  characteristic  instability  of  the  political  boundary  in  disrupted  lin- 
guistic zones  (unless  the  boundary,  as  in  the  case  of  the  Swiss-German 
frontier,  has  weathered  the  storm  over  a  long  period  of  history )  frequently 
generates  expansionist  drives  and  ideologies  on  the  part  of  neighboring 
nations.  These  nations  tend  to  regard  minority  groups  across  the  border 
speaking  their  own  languages  as  akin  and  claim  them  and  their  territory. 
This  is  the  meaning  of  irredentism.  The  term  originated  in  Italy— Italia 
irredenta  (unredeemed  Italy).  A  political  philosophy  of  high  emotional 
pitch,  it  claimed  for  Italy  not  only  neighboring  areas  in  which  Italian  was 
spoken  by  a  majority  of  the  people  ( with  Austria  and  Switzerland  as  tar- 
gets), but  also  lands  across  the  sea,  such  as  Malta  and  the  territory  east 
of  the  Adriatic.  In  countries  in  which  a  nationalistic  irredentism  is  ram- 
pant, we  rarely  find  a  readiness  to  surrender  territory  to  a  neighboring 
country,  even  though  an  alien  language  is  spoken  there.  Thus  Italy,  in  the 
heyday  of  its  irredentist  claims,  did  not  produce  proposals  advocating  the 
surrender  to  Switzerland  and  France  of  the  German-  and  French-speaking 
districts  of  the  Alpine  valleys  of  Piedmont.24  An  extreme  case  of  irre- 
dentism was  presented  by  National  Socialist  Germany  which  started  its 
ill-fated  drive  toward  world  domination  by  irredentist  moves  directed  at 
the  annexation  of  those  regions  along  its  frontier  which  were  inhabited  by 
a  German-speaking  majority:  in  Czechoslovakia  the  Sudetenlands,  the 
Free  State  of  Danzig,  in  Lithuania  the  Memelland,  in  Denmark  the  north- 
ern part  of  Schleswig,  in  Belgium  the  region  of  Eupen-'Malmedy.  The 
"Anschluss"  of  Austria  belongs  in  the  same  category. 

THE  CHANGING  MAP  OF  LANGUAGES:  ERASURE 
OF  LINGUISTIC  POCKETS 

Different  from  the  situation  of  linguistic  minorities  residing  in  areas 
close  to  their  linguistic  or  ethnic  homeland  is  that  of  such  minorities 
occupying  lands  surrounded  entirely  by  territory  inhabited  by  speakers 
of  the  language  prevalent  in  the  country  to  which  they  owe  loyalty.  Here 
the  attraction  and  temptation  which  a  neighboring  linguistic  island  offers 
to  an  expansionist  nation  diminishes  with  the  distance  from  its  borders 
and  with  the  separating  power  of  "foreign"  groups  settled  between  the 

24  H.  B.  George,  The  Relations  of  Geography  and  History,  5th  ed.  (Oxford,  1924), 
p.  57;  see  also  the  detailed  study  of  the  borderlands  of  Italian  language  in  L.  Dominian, 
The  Frontiers  of  Language  and  Nationality  in  Europe  (New  York,  1917),  pp.  59-92. 


THE  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY  OF  LANGUAGES  397 

ethnic  or  linguistic  "homeland"  and  the  related  minority.  Instead,  such 
linguistic  pockets  present  problems  of  internal  political  geography  which, 
especially  in  those  cases  in  which  the  linguistic  or  ethnic  majority  has  to 
deal  with  substantial  minorities,  assume  major  proportions.  The  situation 
differs  from  region  to  region,  nation  to  nation,  and  it  would  be  a  highly 
superficial  undertaking  to  try  and  find  simple  formulas. 

The  existence  of  a  linguistic  pocket  in  close  vicinity  to  the  political 
boundary  of  the  country  in  which  the  same  language  is  prevalent,  often 
leads  to  repressive  measures  against  the  inhabitants  of  the  linguistic 
pocket.  The  radical  solution  consists  in  the  mass  expulsion  of  the  mem- 
bers of  minority  groups  who,  by  remaining  faithful  to  their  mother  tongue 
and  other  features  of  their  minority  culture,  have  actually  or  seemingly 
documented  their  inner  resistance  to  the  state  and  nation  to  which  they 
"belong".  A  more  moderate  solution  is  that  of  international  agreements 
between  the  countries  concerned  aimed  at  an  orderly  population  transfer 
or  exchange.  These  measures  and  the  resulting  radical  changes  in  the 
human  and  consequently  political  structure  of  many  regions  have  assumed 
major  and  decisive  proportions  in  the  political  geography  of  the  twentieth 
century.  Because  of  their  importance,  we  shall  deal  with  them  elsewhere 
separately.25  Here  it  must  suffice  to  point  out  the  quality  of  instability 
of  linguistic  islands,  especially  when  their  inhabitants  continue  to  resist 
cultural  assimilation.  Strong  reactions  may  occur  by  the  majority  against 
what  they  believe  has  remained  a  foreign  element  within  their  political 
entity.  Much  less  noticeable  than  the  effects  of  mass  expulsions  or  popu- 
lation transfers  are  those  changes  in  the  political  landscape  of  a  linguistic 
or  ethnic  pocket  which  result  from  a  gradual  overpowering  of  the  minority 
group  by  strong  immigration  movements.  These  usually  have  government 
support  and  are  aimed  at  eventually  erasing  the  alien  island  from  the 
national  map.  A  case  in  point  is  South  Tyrol.  Its  German-speaking  popu- 
lation complains  that  the  equal  rights  status  promised  to  it  in  the  peace 
treaty  of  1946  exists  in  theory  only  due  to  the  fact  that,  since  1918,  when 
South  Tyrol  became  Italian,  the  Italian  government  has  consistently  spon- 
sored the  mass  migration  of  Italians  into  South  Tyrol  and  thus  the  Italian- 
ization  of  the  region:  the  number  of  Italians  has  risen  between  1918  and 
1954  from  7,000  to  120,000. 

A  full  understanding  of  the  relations  in  political  geography  between 
linguistically  dominant  groups  and  minorities  is  possible  only  if  one 
studies  the  history  and  historical  geography  of  these  relations.  To  under- 
stand, for  instance,  the  geography  of  original  languages  in  America,  we 

25  See  pp.  355  ff. 


398  HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 

must  be  cognizant  of  the  fact  that  when  colonization  started,  America  was 
but  sparsely  settled,  for  the  most  part  by  tribes  in  the  hunting  stage  of 
civilization,  while  the  few  cities  were  subjected  to  ruthless  extermination 
by  the  Spaniards.26  The  Inca  empire  builders  of  the  Andean  universal 
state  displayed  in  their  linguistic  policy  a  different  device  of  authoritarian- 
ism.27 Having  come  to  the  conclusion  that  their  subjects  would  not  func- 
tion as  fully-equipped  human  instruments  of  a  totalitarian  regime  unless 
they  were  equipped  with  some  common  "lingua  franca"— a  supplementary 
language  of  more  than  local  currency— they  selected  the  Quechua  lan- 
guage and  forced  all  the  inhabitants  to  make  themselves  familiar  with  it. 
( An  impressive  example  of  the  importance  of  a  "lingua  franca"  as  a  bind- 
ing element  has  been  the  choice  of  English  as  official  language  at  the  Ban- 
dung conference  of  twenty-eight  Asian  and  African  states  in  April,  1955. ) 

RUSSIFICATION  IN  THE  SOVIET  ORBIT 

The  Soviet  policy  toward  its  ethnic  minorities  and,  as  an  integral  part 
of  it,  the  Russification  of  Soviet  minority  languages  offers  a  significant 
example  of  an  authoritarian  policy  aimed  at  changing  the  linguistic  map 
of  a  nation's  orbit  and,  as  a  result,  changing  also  the  map  of  its  internal 
political  geography.  Enforced  national  conformity  and  ill-concealed  Rus- 
sification are  the  main  characteristics  of  this  policy. 

The  history  of  Soviet  language  policy  is  the  record  of  increasingly  centralized 
manipulation  and  uniformalization  of  the  "forms"  of  supposedly  national  cul- 
tures. The  reins  of  cultural  development  were  taken  away,  after  the  first  decade 
of  Soviet  rule,  from  the  national  minority  leadership,  and  drawn  tight  by  Mos- 
cow. At  first  the  aim  was  to  sever  the  ties  of  the  many  cultural  groups  with  their 
past  and  to  give  their  cultures  a  fresh  Soviet  face;  the  second  step  was  the 
gradual  Russification  of  the  "forms"  of  various  cultures.28 

As  a  rough  approximation,  one  could  say  that  the  Kremlin  has  come  full 
circle  to  imitate  Tsarist  policy  on  national  minorities,  the  essence  of  which 
was  the  imposition  of  the  Russian  language,  church,  and  culture  on  the 
non-Great  Russian  subjects  of  the  empire.29  But  there  are  two  major  dif- 
ferences. "On  the  one  hand,  there  is  the  fact  that  many  scores  of  languages 
today  are  used  in  education  and  publishing  which  were  not  admitted  by 
the  Tsarist  regime.  On  the  other  hand,  the  Soviets  have  added  a  new  twist 
to  the  principle  of  Russification.  The  Tsarist  goal  had  been  the  exclusion 

26  Woolner,  op.  cit.,  p.  15. 

27  A.  J.  Toynbee,  A  Study  of  History,  Vol.  V  (London,  1939),  p.  523. 

28  S.  M.  Schwarz,  "The  Soviet  Concept  and  Conquest  of  National  Cultures," 
Problems  of  Communism  ( 1953),  pp.  41-46. 

29  East  and  Spate,  op.  cit.,  p.  350. 


THE  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY  OF  LANGUAGES  399 

of  minority  languages  from  various  functions  ( education,  literary  usage ) ; 
ultimately,  the  various  ethnic  groups  were  to  end  up  as  Russians.  The 
Soviet  regime,  which  has  slackened  this  approach,  has  launched  the  Russi- 
fication  of  languages.  While  supporting  minority  tongues  in  various  func- 
tions, it  has  subjected  them  to  an  influx  of  Russian  words  and  grammatical 
patterns,  and  has  imposed  on  them  Russian  letters  and  spelling  conven- 
tions." 30 

THE  IMPACT  OF  PHYSICAL  GEOGRAPHY  UPON 
THE  GEOGRAPHY  OF  LANGUAGES 

These  examples  of  authoritarian  language  policy  show  that  there  are 
many  gradations  between  the  extermination  of  minorities  or  their  expul- 
sion or  involuntary  transfer  to  other  regions  within  the  national  bound- 
aries and  remedial  measures  such  as  the  enforcing  of  an  authoritarian 
language  policy  and  a  policy  of  linguistic  laissez  faire.  Choice  as  well  as 
success  or  failure  of  a  government's  measures  are  frequently  conditioned 
by  factors  of  physical  geography.  Often  we  can  trace  the  survival  of  lin- 
guistic islands  among  speakers  of  a  different  tongue— or  even  more  fre- 
quently, the  survival  of  distinct  dialects— to  geographical  features  imped- 
ing easy  communication  between  two  areas.  In  the  secluded  southern 
mountains  of  the  Appalachians,  Shakespearean  language  survived  long 
after  it  had  fallen  into  disuse  in  England  and  in  the  Atlantic  Coastal  Plain 
where  the  mountaineers  once  lived.  So  many  customs  of  the  past  survive 
among  these  people  that  they  have  well  been  called  "our  contemporary 
ancestors."  31  Thus  mountain  chains,  deserts,  forests,  seas,  as  geographi- 
cal features  impeding  communication,  will  lead  us  to  innumerable  loca- 
tions on  the  world's  map  where  from  olden  times  linguistic  pockets  have 
remained  intact  and  where,  consequently— and  in  proportion  to  the  over- 
all national  importance  of  these  islands— problems  of  internal  and  external 
political  geography  stayed  alive. 

On  the  other  hand,  the  relationship  of  physical  and  human  geography, 
in  terms  of  the  political  geography  of  languages,  is  not  so  obvious  that 
the  physiographical  map  provides  most  of  the  answers  to  the  questions  of 
why  and  where.  By  no  means  do  linguistic  boundaries  always  follow 
obvious  geographical  lines.32  To  claim  33  that  linguistic  lines  of  cleavage 

30  U.  Weinreich,  "The  Russification  of  Soviet  Minority  Languages,"  Problems  of 
Communism  (1953),  pp.  46-57  (47). 

31  E.  C.  Semple,  "The  Anglo-Saxons  of  the  Kentucky  Mountains,"  Geographical 
Journal  (1901),  pp.  588-623. 

32  Woolner,  op.  cit.,  pp.  15-16. 

33  Dominian,  op.  cit.,  pp.  2-3. 


400  HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 

conform  essentially  with  physical  features  would  be  a  gross  oversimplifi- 
cation of  the  problem.  In  present-day  human  geography  these  features  are 
significant  in  many  cases;  they  are  not  significant  in  many  others. 
For  Europe,  W.  Gordon  East 34  describes  this  as  follows: 

.  .  .  the  lower  Danube,  flanked  by  a  broad  belt  of  marshes  on  its  north  bank, 
does  divide  Rumanian  from  Rulgarian-speaking  peoples.  The  boundary  between 
French  and  German  passes  along  the  wooded  summits  from  the  high  Vosges. 
The  area  of  the  Pripet  marshes  separates  Ukranian  and  Belorussian  speech,  and 
the  Pyrenees  effectively  separate  French  and  Spanish.  Areas  of  scantily  settled 
steppe  and  rivers  which  are  unnavigable  upstream,  characterize  the  frontier 
region  between  Portuguese  and  Spanish.  But,  in  the  main,  peoples  and  lan- 
guages have  negotiated  physical  obstacles  such  as  mountains,  rivers,  highlands, 
and  marshes.  The  watershed  of  the  Alps  does  not  neatly  divide  French  and 
German  from  Italian;  within  the  Alpine  valleys,  distinctive  languages  have  de- 
veloped in  semi-isolation;  neither  do  the  eastern  Pyrenees  sharply  divide  the 
areas  of  Catalan  and  Provencal.  As  to  the  navigable  rivers  of  Europe,  they  com- 
monly serve  to  unite  rather  than  to  divide,  so  that  the  Vistula  Basin  forms  the 
core  region  of  Polish  speech  while  that  of  the  Rhine  has  become  mainly  Ger- 
manic, yet  invaded  by  French  on  its  western  flank.  The  Danube,  in  contrast, 
presents  a  succession  of  language  areas  astride  its  valley. 

In  lowlands  and  hilly  country,  the  frontiers  of  language  bear  no  obvious  rela- 
tionship to  the  relief  and  are  clearly  the  expression  of  social  forces  operative 
long  ago.  Even  so,  former  geographical  features— now  erased— may  have  been 
significant:  thus  the  former  Carbonniere  Forest  did  in  medieval  times  form  a 
zone  of  separation  between  Flemish  speech  in  the  Scheldt  Basin  and  French 
speech  to  the  south. 

THE  MOVEMENT  OF  PEOPLES  AND  THE  LINGUISTIC  FACTOR 

Europe's  language  map,  like  those  of  its  nations  and  states,  can  be  explained 
only  in  terms  of  historical  geography,  i.e.,  the  movements  of  peoples,  their  initial 
settlements  and  subsequent  colonization  outwards,  and  their  mutual  reactions 
when  brought  into  contact  with  each  other.  By  the  end  of  the  Middle  Ages  the 
language  patterns  were  clearly  outlined;  one  can  point  to  specific  linguistic 
frontiers,  notably  that  of  French  and  German  in  the  Lorraine  Plateau  and  that 
of  Walloon  and  French  on  the  Franco-Belgian  border  where  the  boundary  has 
changed  but  little  during  the  last  thousand  years.  And,  since  the  end  of  the 
Middle  Ages,  the  many  migrations,  colonizing  efforts,  and  compulsory  and  vol- 
untary transfers  of  population,  especially  in  the  last  decade,  have  modified  dis- 
tributions fixed  long  ago. 


35 


In  our  age  of  technology,  more  and  more  natural  obstructions  are  being 
crossed;  the  impact  of  radio  makes  itself  felt  in  the  most  remote  hamlets. 
Colonization,  in  particular  settlement  colonization  of  the  tropics,  has  led 
to  the  crossing  of  oceans  by  languages.  It  is  here  where  historical  geog- 

34  In  G.  W.  Hoffman,  ed.,  A  Geography  of  Europe  (New  York,  1953),  pp.  30-31. 
Copyright  1953,  The  Ronald  Press  Company. 
a5  East,  op.  cit. 


THE  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY  OF  LANGUAGES  401 

raphy  offers  the  most  striking  examples  of  an  immense  variety  of  invasion 
forces  displayed  by  foreign  language  groups  from  distant  lands.  The 
spread  of  the  Greek  language  followed  colonization.  Greek  cities  scattered 
from  older  centers  round  the  shores  of  the  Mediterranean,  mainly  in  the 
eastern  half  but  also  as  far  west  as  southern  Italy  and  Marseilles.36 

The  Roman  Empire  carried  its  language  far  beyond  the  Italian  penin- 
sula, and  in  the  Roman  colonia  (colony),  where  conquered  lands  were 
allotted  to  Roman  veterans,  we  find  the  soldiers  of  the  Roman  legions  and 
the  traders  introducing  their  own  language  and  civilization  to  the  bar- 
barians.37 Wherever  Roman  colonizers  went,  their  prestige  and  the  proud 
Roman  civilization  which  they  represented,  as  well  as  their  close-knit  and 
organized  social  community  (conventus  civium  Romanorum)  endowed 
the  Roman  language  (and  Roman  law)  with  a  privileged  position.38  Thus 
Latin  was  adopted  in  Western  Europe,  North  Africa,  and  in  Central 
Europe,  up  to  the  Rhine-Limes-Danube  frontier  zone— the  outer  defense 
curtain  from  Castra  Regina  (Regensburg)  to  Confluentes  (Coblenz).  In 
Western  Europe  the  transformative  force  of  the  Roman  language  proved 
decisive  and  permanent.  Provincial  Latin  conditioned  the  growth  during 
the  Middle  Ages  of  languages  of  the  Romance  group:  French,  Provencal, 
Italian,  Catalan,  Spanish,  and  Portuguese.  In  the  Swiss  mountains,  islands 
of  Latin  weathered  the  impact  of  centuries.  In  Rumania,  in  what  once 
formed  the  Roman  province  of  Dacia,  an  "inlier"  of  Roman  speech,  con- 
taining some  Slav  elements,  remained  alive.39 

The  historical  geography  of  Roman  colonization  and  its  impact  on  the 
languages  of  the  Romance  group,  however  important,  is  only  one  instance 
of  how  language  patterns  and  linguistic  frontiers  evolve  as  the  result  of 
invasions  and  conquests,  oversea  and  overland  colonization.  The  student 
of  the  history  of  languages  and  of  historical  geography  will  find  here  vast 
fields  to  plow,  and  often  enough  in  what  is  scientifically  no  man's  land.  To 
the  student  of  political  geography  this  background  is  of  great  interest  and 
in  many  cases,  as  evidenced  by  India,  is  indispensable.  Here  it  must  suffice 
to  stress  the  importance  of  the  historical  events  which  account  for  the 
survival  of  linguistic  islands  within  nations  the  majority  of  whose  people 
are  speakers  of  a  different  tongue,  and  also  to  emphasize  the  problems 
of  internal  and  external  geography  generated  by  these  language  pockets. 

36  Woolner,  op.  cit.,  p.  14. 

37  Ibid.,  pp.  13-14. 

38  I.  Mommsen,  Romische  Geschichte,  Vol.  II  (1857),  p.  407. 

39  East,  op.  cit.,  pp.  25-26. 


402  HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 

DIALECTS 

The  political  geography  of  languages  applies  also  to  dialects,  especially 
in  regard  to  the  internal  political  geography  of  nations.  Professor  Mario 
Pei  reports  that  about  half  the  students  in  linguistic  classes  who  were 
polled  as  to  their  native  tongue  replied  "American"  rather  than  "Eng- 
lish," 40  and  G.  B.  Shaw  wisecracked  in  Pygmalion  that  "England  and 
America  are  two  countries  separated  by  the  same  language."  These  ob- 
servations and  the  distinctions,  well  known  to  Americans,  between  New 
England  ("Yankee")  and  Southern  American  dialects  bring  home  to  the 
reader  the  importance  of  dialects  within  the  framework  of  the  geography 
of  languages.  The  borderline  between  language  and  dialect  is  exceedingly 
thin  and  the  usual  distinction  between  a  language  as  the  accepted  national 
form  of  speech  and  dialect  as  the  not  officially  accepted  form  is  not  too 
helpful.  In  Switzerland,  for  instance,  both  German  and  the  dialect  known 
as  Schwyzer-Deutsch  are  recognized  officially  and  taught  in  the  schools. 
Each  language  has  "infinite  gradations  of  standard  tongue,  vernacular, 
slang,  cant,  and  jargon,"  and  the  "geographical  division  extends  not  only 
to  regions  and  sections  of  the  country,  but  also  to  towns  and  quarters  of 
focus."  41  It  is  obvious  that  the  use  of  the  same  dialect  generates  strong 
feelings  of  belonging-together  among  its  speakers  and  also  contributes  to 
setting  them  apart  from  other  folk  groups  who,  while  speaking  and  writ- 
ing the  same  language,  have  a  different  dialect.  Within  a  nation,  the 
separating  factors  due  to  differences  in  dialect  may  be  insignificant  politi- 
cally because  other,  unifying,  factors  are  overwhelming.  Or  they  may  be 
powerful  enough  to  build  invisible  walls  between  the  various  dialect 
groups. 

To  the  student  of  political  geography  who  attempts  to  trace  the  geo- 
graphical distribution  of  languages  on  the  political  map  and  to  understand 
the  relationship  of  geography  and  language,  it  will  thus  be  evident  that, 
especially  in  the  internal  political  geography  of  states,  he  cannot  neglect 
the  consideration  of  the  unifying  and  separating  force  of  dialects.  When 
millions  of  so-called  ethnic  Germans  were  expelled  from  Czechoslovakia 
and  Poland  in  1945  and  later,  the  problems  confronting  the  West  German 
government  in  its  task  of  resettling  the  destitute  expellees  in  the  north, 
south  and  southwest  of  Germany  were  multiplied  by  the  fact  that  the  new 
German  citizens  spoke  dialects  alien  to  the  Germans  who  were  to  receive 


40  Pei,  op.  cit.,  p,  298. 

41  Ibid.,  pp.  46-47. 


THE  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY  OF  LANGUAGES  403 

the  refugees  in  their  communities.  Germany  itself  has  two  great  language 
divisions:  High  German  and  Low  German,  as  well  as  numerous  local  vari- 
ations. Its  map  of  languages  and  dialects  with  all  its  political  implications 
is,  as  the  result  of  the  influx  of  millions  of  ethnic-German  expellees,  under- 
going radical  changes.  As  settlement  of  compact  groups  of  newcomers 
with  dialects  of  their  own  becomes  stabilized,  new  linguistic  islands  will 
be  formed— islands  of  distinctive  dialects  within  the  national  boundaries 
of  Germany,  and  possessing  all  the  characteristics  of  a  nationality  group 
bound  together  by  common  memories,  ideals,  and  hopes.  An  interesting, 
although  older,  linguistic  island  of  this  kind  within  Germany  is  its  indus- 
trial heartland,  the  Ruhr,  with  a  total  population  of  about  seven  million. 
Its  mining  population  is  composed  of  many  ethnic  groups,  especially  from 
Eastern  Germany  and  Poland.  Gradually  it  has  assumed  distinctive  na- 
tional characteristics  of  its  own,  and  in  this  process  has  developed  a  new 
dialect,  a  mixture  of  Westphalian,  East  Prussian,  Upper-Silesian,  and  High 
German.  The  speakers  of  the  new  tongue  share  an  intangible  possession 
which  contributes  strongly  to  the  evolution  of  a  specific  folk-group  within 
the  entity  of  the  nation. 

Italy  is  rich  in  dialects  which  set  a  distinguishing  pattern  of  human 
geography:  Sicilian,  Neapolitan,  Roman,  Tuscan,  Venetian,  and  the  Gallo- 
Italian  dialects  of  northwestern  Italy.42 

China  offers  the  most  colorful  illustration  of  a  country  divided  into  a 
large  number  of  dialects  often  mutually  unintelligible  though  falling  into 
the  broad  categories  of  Northern  and  Southern  43  (Fig.  11-3).  About  three 
hundred  million  people  speak  variants  of  Mandarin,  the  dialect  of  north- 
ern China,  now  renamed  Kiio-yii  or  "National  Tongue";  the  remaining  one 
hundred  fifty  million  speak  widely  divergent  dialects,  the  majority  of 
which  are  Cantonese,  the  Wu  dialect  of  Shanghai,  and  the  Klin  dialect  of 
Fukien.44  Thus,  while  the  possession  of  a  common  written  language  pro- 
vides the  Chinese  with  an  asset  making  for  unity,  the  multiplicity  of  dia- 
lects is  a  potent  factor  of  separation  which  can  be  overcome  gradually  only 
if  the  northern  form  of  the  "National  Tongue,"  as  a  national  lingua  franca, 
should  be  accepted  on  a  broad  national  basis.45 


42  Pei,  op.  cit.,  p.  54. 

43  Gray,  op.  cit.,  p.  390. 


44  Pei,  op.  cit.,  p.  371;  P.  M.  Roxby,  "China  as  an  Entity,"  Geography  (1937), 
pp.  1-20. 

45  H.  J.  Wood,  in  East  and  Spate,  op.  cit.,  pp.  265-266.  For  a  vivid  description  of 
the  contrast  between  the  Mandarin  lingua  franca  and  the  highly  diversified  local 
dialects,  see  Toynbee,  op.  cit.,  Vol.  V,  pp.  512-514. 


404 


HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 


Fig.  11-3.  China:  Areas  of  Languages  and  Dialects:  (1)  Northern  Mandarin;  (2) 
Southern  Mandarin;  (3)  Mongolian;  (4)  Tibetan;  (5)  Tribal  dialects;  (6)  Can- 
tonese;  (7)   Hakka;   (8)   Fukien  dialects;   (9)   Wu  dialects   (after  P.  M.  Roxby). 

From  the  abstract  point  of  view,  the  multilingual  state  is  not  ideal. 
Germs  of  disunity  similar  to  those  existing  unavoidably  in  the  multi- 
lingual state  will  be  found  in  states  where  local  dialects  have  remained 
strong  enough  to  challenge  the  supremacy  of  the  national  language.  In 
either  case  the  student  of  political  geography  should  take  cognizance  of 
these  linguistic  patterns  which  spell  both  unity  and  disunity  and  which 
therefore  must  be  understood  if  one  tries  to  evaluate  the  human  and 
political  geography  of  a  nation. 


CHAPTER 


n 


Religions:  Their  Distribution 
and  Role  in  Political  Geography 


THE  IMPACT  OF  RELIGION  UPON  POLITICS  IN  HISTORY 

A  few  centuries  ago  political  boundaries  throughout  the  world  coin- 
cided closely  with  religious  boundaries.  Still  more  important,  religious 
differences  found  expression  in,  and  were  more  or  less  temporarily  settled 
by,  political  conflicts.  On  the  other  hand,  political  conflicts  influenced 
religious  thought  and  religious  allegiance.  At  the  beginning  of  written 
history  the  political  unification  of  the  numerous  small  states  of  the  Nile 
valley  into  a  unified  kingdom  led  to  the  belief  in  a  hierarchy  of  gods,  in 
which  the  local  gods  became  subordinate  minor  deities.  This  process  has 
been  repeated,  with  characteristic  variations,  but  basically  along  similar 
lines  in  some  other  countries.  Conquests  led  to  changes  in  worship,  be- 
cause both  the  conquered  and  the  conqueror  shared  the  conviction  that 
the  god  of  the  victorious  group  had  proved  to  have  greater  power  not  only 
at  home  but  even  in  the  territory  of  the  defeated  god.  Some  religions 
required  their  followers  to  spread  their  beliefs  by  the  sword.  Islam  is  the 
prototype  of  such  a  religion.  The  spread  of  early  Islam  inevitably  led  to 
the  expansion  of  Arab  rule.  In  such  periods  a  map  of  religious  affiliations 
would  disclose  the  geographical  distribution  and  extent  of  political  forces 
better  than  would  a  map  of  kingdoms,  which  would  at  best  show  short- 
lived dynastic  combinations. 

It  is  therefore  significant  for  us  that,  in  early  history  and  even  today 
among  primitive  people,  the  religious  community  precedes,  and  later 

405 


406  HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 

often  supersedes,  the  political  community.1  To  see  to  what  extent  factors 
of  the  natural  environment  have  influenced  the  context  and  the  extent  of 
religious  communities,  to  visualize  the  boundaries  which  separate  these 
communities— as  forerunners  of  national  communities  or  in  competition  or 
co-ordination  with  them— from  other  cultural  or  national  groups  is  essen- 
tial for  the  understanding  of  many  problems  of  historical  geography. 
From  this  perception  it  is  but  one  step  to  the  recognizing  of  many  present- 
day  problems  of  state  power  and  conflict  in  which  religion,  and  in  par- 
ticular organized  religion,  plays  a  part. 

THE  RELATIONSHIP  OF  RELIGIOUS  DISTRIRUTION  AND 
POLITICAL  FACTORS  TODAY 

Periods  in  which  the  religious  community  was  dominant  alternated  with 
periods  during  which  politics  was  swayed  by  different  motivations.  Our 
own  age  is  such  an  era,  characterized  by  the  interplay  of  complex  and 
conflicting  motivations.  Therefore,  we  have  to  determine  in  this  chapter 
whether  and  to  what  extent  religious  distribution  coincides  with  political 
units:  are  such  instances  merely  historical  relics?  Can  and  would  religious 
distribution  and  loyalties  affect  the  political  map  of  today?  If  so  to  what 
extent?  Can  and  would  political  changes  affect  religious  allegiances  under 
present-day  conditions? 

The  first  question  can  be  approached  by  comparing  one  of  the  cus- 
tomary maps  of  religious  distribution  with  a  political  map.  For  a  number 
of  reasons  we  have  to  call  such  a  map  a  preliminary  approximation.  A 
large  part  of  the  globe's  surface  lacks  reliable  statistics  of  religious  affilia- 
tion. We  have  only  very  rough  estimates  for  the  more  than  a  quarter  of 
humanity  which  lives  in  the  Soviet  Union  and  China.  The  picture  is  even 
more  complicated  by  the  fact  that  the  available  statistical  sources,  al- 
though they  reveal  certain  information  about  the  geographical  distribu- 
tion of  organized  churches,  can  reveal  but  very  little  concerning  the 
religious  beliefs  of  individuals  and  communities  and  because  of  this  de- 
ficiency can  be  misleading.  There  is  no  accepted  standard  for  reporting 
religious  adherences.  In  some  cases,  particularly  among  Roman  Catholics, 
all  those  baptized  or  even  all  those  coming  from  a  family  of  the  same 
faith,  are  counted  as  Roman  Catholics.  In  other  churches,  only  those 
confirmed  or  baptized  in  adulthood  are  reported.  These  differences  are 
trifling  in  comparison  with  the  greater  problem  of  how  to  relate  the  sta- 
tistics of  religions  to  the  actual  beliefs  of  individuals.  For  instance,  in 

1  F.  Ratzel,  op.  cit.,  pp.  164-167. 


RELIGIONS:  THEIR  DISTRIBUTION  AND  ROLE  407 

West  Germany  official  statistics  show  that  96.3  per  cent  of  the  population 
are  Protestants  or  Roman  Catholics— 51.1  per  cent  Protestant  and  45.2 
per  cent  Roman  Catholic.  But  a  public-opinion  sampling  in  1951  indicated 
that  only  78  per  cent  of  the  population  actually  "believed  in  God,"  and 
that  only  62  per  cent  of  these  "believed  in  Jesus  as  the  Son  of  God."  In 
the  Scandinavian  countries,  it  is  reported,  Protestant  pastors  say  that  not 
more  than  one-tenth  of  the  average  parish  betrays  any  lively  interest  in 
the  church.  In  a  poll  taken  in  1952  in  an  area  of  Norway  where  church 
loyalty  was  considered  above  average,  60  per  cent  of  the  young  Nor- 
wegians questioned  said  that  they  were  not  much  interested  in  Chris- 
tianity, 14  per  cent  declared  themselves  Christians,  and  25  per  cent  said 
they  were  well  disposed  toward  the  Christian  faith.  These  facts  contrast 
with  the  official  Norwegian  statistics,  according  to  which  out  of  a  popula- 
tion of  3.2  million  in  1946  there  were  only  100,000  dissidents  from  the 
Lutheran  National  Church.  In  England,  where  the  Church  of  England  is 
the  center  of  the  world-wide  Anglican  communion,  we  find  that  the  Estab- 
lished Church,  which  baptizes  some  two-thirds  of  the  children  born  in 
England,  counts  only  2.3  million  members  out  of  a  population  of  43.7 
million  (1951).2  One  of  the  few  existing  detailed  studies  on  this  subject 
shows  that  in  a  typical  French  provincial  town,  nominally  almost  one  hun- 
dred per  cent  Catholic,  only  15,000  of  130,000  inhabitants  go  to  mass.3  In 
an  industrial  environment  in  France  it  was  found  that  only  four  out  of 
19,000  men  employed  in  one  industrial  complex  were  practicing  Catho- 
lics.4 These  facts  can  be  paralleled  for  every  country  publishing  statistics 
on  church  membership,  and  they  should  be  kept  in  mind  when  using  such 
statistics,  or  church  distribution  maps,  for  the  evaluation  of  political  fac- 
tors. 

Spain  and  Portugal,  as  well  as  France,  appear  on  a  church  distribution 
map  as  overwhelmingly  Roman  Catholic  countries.  However,  this  should 
not  lead  to  the  conclusion  that  they  constitute  a  unified  bloc.  It  is  clear 
that  Spain's  international  policy  is  influenced  strongly  by  religious  con- 
victions; in  1954  the  Spanish  government  endangered  much-coveted  mili- 
tary aid  from  the  United  States  rather  than  yield  on  religious  principles. 
Spain  is  a  country  where  the  ruling  group  is  firmly  rooted  in  the  Catholic 
faith.  The  allegiance  of  the  masses  to  Catholicism  appears  to  be  less  pro- 
nounced, as  evidenced  in  the  repeated  church-burning  episodes  of  the  last 
150  years.  In  Portugal  the  peasants  seem  to  be  firmer  in  their  Catholic 

2  S.  W.  Herman,  Report  From  Christian  Europe  (New  York,  1953),  pp.  155,  48,  49. 

3  J.  Perrot,  Grenoble,  Essay  de  Sociologie  Religieuse  (Grenoble,  1953). 

4  R.  F.  Byrnes,  "The  French  Priest-Workers,"  Foreign  Affairs,  Vol-  33  (January, 
1955),  p.  327. 


408  HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 

faith.  Portugal  has  tried,  with  some  success,  to  build  a  corporative  state 
following  the  lines  laid  out  in  the  Papal  Encyclical,  Quadragesimo  Anno. 
In  France  a  complete  separation  of  Church  and  State  has  taken  place,  and 
a  great  majority  of  Frenchmen  seem  to  be  Catholic  only  in  name.  A 
politico-religious  map,  in  order  to  be  useful,  would  have  to  distinguish 
among  these  three  countries  as  three  different  politico-religious  types: 
Spain,  dominated  by  a  strongly  Catholic  laity  and  adhering  to  traditional 
forms  of  political  life;  Portugal,  a  country  where  Catholicism  is  reshaping 
the  social  and  economic  life;  and  France,  a  nominally  Catholic  country 
where  Catholicism  has  influence  only  upon  and  through  one  of  the  more 
important  political  parties.  As  far  as  Catholicism  has  any  influence  upon 
domestic  or  international  policy  in  France,  it  is  an  indication  of  the 
strength  of  this  party  in  the  government  of  the  moment  rather  than  an 
indication  of  the  fact  that  99  per  cent  of  the  French  population  are 
counted  as  Catholics. 

These  examples  show  also  that  political  boundaries  are  in  certain  cases 
good  indications  of  the  distribution  of  certain  religious  attitudes.  They 
show  also  that  political  attitudes  are  influenced,  both  positively  and  nega- 
tively, by  the  hold  religion  has  on  the  population  as  a  whole,  on  a  ruling 
group,  or  on  the  government.  Of  the  eighty-three  independent  or  semi- 
dependent  countries  of  the  earth  ( see  Table  I ) ,  fifty  are  countries  where 
90  per  cent  or  more  of  the  population  belong  to  the  same  religion.  This 
gives  us  a  first  approximation  of  the  extent  to  which  maps  of  religious 
affiliations  and  maps  of  political  units  coincide.  It  does  not  necessarily 
mean  that  the  religious  affiliation  of  a  population  determines  its  political 
attitudes.  However,  there  is  hardly  a  country  containing  a  significant 
religious  minority  where  this  factor  has  no  political  significance.  In  some 
cases  such  religious  minority  status  has  hindered  the  assimilation  of  na- 
tional groups:  Armenians,  Jews,  French  Canadians,  Irish  Catholics  and 
many  other  groups  have  preserved  their  separate  existence  primarily  be- 
cause of  religious  differences.  These  differences  are  often  an  obstacle  to 
intermarriage.  Religious  minorities  sometimes  form  separate  political  par- 
ties, or  as  a  group  back  the  party  friendliest  to  themselves.  Poles  in  Ger- 
many were  among  the  most  reliable  followers  of  the  Catholic  Center 
Party,  the  Lutherans  in  Austria  of  the  German  National  Party.  The  Alsa- 
tians could  not  easily  be  assimilated  into  the  main  body  of  the  French, 
not  so  much  because  of  their  German  dialect  but  because  of  their  strong 
Catholic  allegiance  in  a  religiously  indifferent  France. 

No  existing  map  of  the  distribution  of  religions  can  show  an  even 
approximately  correct  picture  for  the  Soviet  Union  and  the  affiliated 


RELIGIONS:  THEIR  DISTRIBUTION  AND  ROLE  409 

Peoples'  Republics.  Not  only  has  no  religious  census  been  taken  in  these 
countries  for  many  years;  we  can  only  state  with  some  degree  of  assurance 
that  since  the  last  census  an  unknown  number  of  individuals  have  relin- 
quished their  original  religious  affiliation,  and  that  to  all  appearances 
many  young  people  have  grown  up  without  any  real  contact  with  a 
church. 


THE  MULTITUDE  OF  RELIGIOUS  DENOMINATIONS 

Another,  though  remediable  and  therefore  minor,  defect  of  practically 
all  existing  maps  of  religious  distribution  on  a  continental  or  world-wide 
scale  is  their  oversimplification.  Most  maps  attempt  to  show  a  broad-brush 
picture  of  the  distribution  of  major  religions,  taking  uniformity  in  doctrine 
rather  than  diversity  in  organization  as  their  differentiating  feature  (Fig. 
12-1 ) .  However,  many  religions  are  deeply  split  into  dissenting  and  some- 
times hostile  denominations. 

In  the  United  States,  we  have  the  strongest  evidence  of  the  wide  variety 
of  Protestant  churches.  Two  hundred  and  fifty-two  different  Protestant 
religious  bodies  were  reported  in  1952.  While  there  is  no  unity  in  Ameri- 
can Protestantism,  it  would  be  misleading  to  assume  that  the  seeming 
disunity  of  the  American  churches  as  evidenced  by  the  large  number  of 
Protestant  denominations  is  in  the  nature  of  a  serious  schism.  A  large 
nucleus  of  28  churches  belongs  to  the  National  Council  of  the  Churches 
of  Christ  in  the  U.S.A.  The  non-co-operative  fringe  contains  some  large 
conservative  bodies  such  as  the  Southern  Baptists  and  the  Missouri  Synod 
Lutherans,  and  some  large  bodies  such  as  the  Mormons  and  Christian 
Scientists,  but  most  of  the  fringe  is  represented  by  some  two  hundred 
small  sects  which  account  for  only  2  per  cent  of  all  Protestants.  The  con- 
sciousness, throughout  the  Western  world,  of  the  impressive  unity  of  the 
Catholic  Church  is  the  indirect  cause  of  a  common  misconception  which 
assumes  a  similar  kind  of  unity  for  other  religions.  This  misconception  is 
supported  by  the  oversimplification  of  most  maps  depicting  the  distribu- 
tion of  religions.  Especially  where  religions  and  political  factors  are 
closely  linked,  the  resulting  errors  may  lead  to  a  distorted  evaluation  of 
the  political  map  and  of  international  relations  as  influenced  by  religious 
factors. 

A  case  in  point  is  the  world  of  Islam  (cf.  Fig.  12-5,  p.  426).  Character- 
istic of  the  widespread  ignorance  ( in  the  western  world )  of  Islamic  condi- 
tions is  the  now  almost  forgotten  incident  of  Tangier  in  1905.  William  II, 
German  emperor,  almost  wrecked  the  main  purpose  of  his  Mediterranean 


s 
"8 

3 


i— I 
to 


410 


RELIGIONS:   THEIR  DISTRIBUTION  AND  ROLE  411 

cruise  of  that  year— the  strengthening  of  his  ties  with  Turkey— by  stressing 
in  a  speech  in  Tangier  the  complete  sovereignty  of  the  Sherif  of  Morocco. 
Though  the  demonstration  was  intended  against  France,  William  did  not 
know  that  the  Sherif  was  regarded  by  the  Grand  Sultan  of  Turkey  as  a 
schismatic  who  did  not  recognize  the  Sultan's  Khalifat  supremacy.  The 
Islamic  world  is  deeply  split  by  the  hostility  of  Sunnites  and  Shiites.  Iran, 
the  only  major  Shiite  country,  is  relatively  unaffected  by  appeals  from  the 
rest  of  the  Moslem  world.  Iraq  is  divided  between  these  two  sects,  with 
the  Sunnites  more  important  politically.  Little,  remote  Oman  has  its  own 
Islamic  denomination,  seldom  found  outside  its  boundaries. 

Still  less  known  is  the  geographical  distribution  of  Hindu  sects  in  India 
( cf.  Fig.  12-3,  p.  420 ) .  Buddhism  in  Ceylon,  Burma,  and  Thailand  may  be 
regarded  as  belonging  to  the  same  denomination  despite  the  lack  of  com- 
mon organizational  ties.  Tibetan  or  Mongolian  Lamaistic  Buddhism,  how- 
ever, is  entirely  different,  and  the  Buddhism  of  China  and  especially  of 
Japan  is  different  again  5  and  is  split  into  many  denominations,  some  non 
political,  others,  like  Japanese  Zen-Buddhism,  intensively  occupied  with 
active  political  attitudes.  These  differences  have  never  been  adequately 
mapped— the  first  condition  for  a  safe  geographical  approach. 

The  following  table  tries  to  refine  somewhat  the  rough  approximation 
at  which  a  map  could  arrive.  The  data  in  the  table  are  taken  mainly  from 
the  Statesman's  Yearbooks  of  1953  and  1954.  However,  the  sources  of  this 
yearbook,  though  presumably  the  best  available,  are  of  widely  varying 
accuracy  and  different  date. 

POLITICAL  AND  RELIGIOUS  BOUNDARIES;  THEIR 

RELATIONSHIP 

Table  12-1  shows  that  a  majority  of  countries  are  for  all  practical  pur- 
poses religiously  uniform.  It  shows  also  that  there  is  a  surprisingly  large 
number  of  countries  which  are  unique  in  the  religious  composition  of 
their  population.  The  major  religion  of  many  of  these  countries  is  almost 
unknown  to  the  rest  of  the  world.  The  number  of  such  countries  is  even 
larger  if  we  include  the  considerable  number  where  doctrinal  uniformity 
may  go  hand  in  hand  with  separate  organization.  Lutheran  Germany, 
Sweden,  Norway,  Denmark,  Finland,  and  Iceland  have  not  only  separate 
church  organizations,  but  they  also  use  different  languages  in  their  serv- 

5  A.  J.  Toynbee,  in  A  Study  of  History  ( 1934-54 )  in  many  places  avoids,  therefore, 
the  term  Buddhism  in  favor  of  Mahayana  when  speaking  of  this  northern  Buddhism, 
and  of  the  Tantric  form  of  Buddhism  when  speaking  of  Tibetan  and  related  forms. 


w 
3 


•§ 

^X 

0) 

3 

J>-> 

cS 

CA 

-Q 

O 

>M 

CO 

o 

Cm 

cS 

mQ 

O 

<a 

<u 

CL, 

JS 

m 

J3  & 

3 

-D 

o" 

Oi 
i—l 

3 

03 

-°k_" 

CO 

CO 

^2 
'c3 

03 

•1— 1 

173 

03 

•H 

03 

S 

4-» 
CO 

03  t> 

03  C5 

CD 
H 

13 

CD 

lM 

3 

> 

> 

s 

> 

CD 

c 

3 

>  i-l 

s 

60 

bO 

ca 

CS 

o 

MM 

03 

o 

O 

03  v^ 

o 

CO 

ca 

CO 

0) 

co 

CD 

'3d 

O 

co 
(Li 

CD 
3 

'5b '3c 

en    O 

£  a; 

'3d 

13 

"rt 

l^ 

;m 

CD 

}h 

1— H 

CD 

CD 

•4M 
43 

s 

bC 

3 
b£ 

CD 

03 

s 

4M 

— H 

3 

bC 

CD 

CD 
SM 

figu: 
imat 

CD 
u 

o 

£6 

« 

C3 

0 

•4-» 

en 

|H 

43 

■4-1 

0) 

3 

CD 
■H 

o 

o 

o 

O 

03 

to 

o 

o 

o3 

ca 

O   to 

CO 
mD 
O 

03 

o 

o 

55 

55 

-4-» 

w 

o 

CO 

55 

55 

4M 

-M* 

2W 

JM 
CO 

55 

55 

CD 


cm 

i-H 
W 

S3 


CO 

I 

w 

K 

H 

Z 

o 

I— 1 

M 

z 
o  ^ 

CO     2 

« 
o 

o 
o 


o 

.~ 

,3 

fcS 

-t-> 

CD 

a 

CO 

O 

1 

s 

s 

CO 

p 

03 
O 

o 

,lp 

PES 

bO 
3  ..~ 

{£ 

^  oo 

i— i 

•  •  1—1 

CM 

CO        [ 

l 

*->      \ 

1 

3    H 

X 

3  cj 

o 

-^  33 

T3 

CD     2 

-M*    lE 

O 

]M 

°  "S 

12 
o 

i_     03 
Cm  U 

bJO  p 

rM 

a  ca 

CD 
CD 

lM 

i  § 

o 

<PS 

cm 


I 

.s 
a 


CO 

O 


6S  CM 

W?  I 

|  co 

co  3 

+J  03 


•*     s  -a 

co  5    E 

£  Sm3 


s 

03 


O  CD 
Cm     I 

§  s 

£  « 

CO 

O 


*  i 
CJ 

o  o  « 

^5  3  &S> 

U  O  CM 

E^  3 

03  CD  ,3 

O  3  -3 

PCS  £)  ffi 


155 
CD 


Dm 
O 

u 
>^ 

p 

03 

s 

co" 

3 

CTS 


lM 

,3 

u 


o 


0 

IS 
0 


w 
PC 


o 

-M» 

CCi 

u 


cc 

CO      co" 

s  s 

CD     CD 


O 

I 

CJ   &S 


^T? 


3  CM 


CO      co 
O     O 

O     CD 


3    3 

S    a 
3    3 

CO  OO 


-S  -f!     O   CO 


s  ^ 

03    cci 

.SO 


3 
-  * 
3   w 

2    CD 

Js 

EC  Cm 


o 

fM 

C8 

u 

3 

ca 

E 
o 
PC 


05 


O     CJ 


O 

3  ^ 

3   +J 
03    o3 

.So 

E  3 

O  03 

T3  P 

CD  5 

lM  2 

Pm  Pm 


O  in 

-S  °o 

"5  I 

U  g 

3  T3 

03  O 

°  i 

Pm  O 


00 


3 
CQ 


-3 
T3 

3 

-Im^W 

3     I 

S  « 

.S    3 


^§  iS 

CD     O 

•—     — 
Pm  Cm 


05 


Tf    o 

0?m3 


3 

PQ 


3 

a 

s 

o 

Cm 


o   cj 


o 

_s 

CS 

O 

3 

ca 

E 
o 
Pm 


O 

m3 


6    3^ 
03    03    03    o3 

uu.Su 

3    E 

03    O 
T3 


P 

ca 

E 

o 


CD 


3 
03 

£ 

o 


o 

m3 


OS  PCS  Cm  PCS 


ca         3 

U        | 

3  &S    O 

2  <-*  Pm 

E  05  T^ 

o 

J  1  ^ 

Cm    g    co 

99% 
holi 

1   "5 

mina 
tic  M 

;t  exc 
lie 

!r    3 

<Q    o3 

O   -3    o    ° 

T3    3    §  J5 

CD    3    p    *± 

^    S 

3    O 

S    3  -^    « 

J  Cm 

Pmco  <3  O 

iz; 

o 

CJ 


3 

Ea 


3  .2 

2  3 
-3  ctf 
bJD  n 

MM    3i 


ca 

3 

3  -C 

CD  *3 
bJD  » 

Ih  3 

<  < 


3  .a, 


>M 

4^ 

■€h.Ss 

3 

CD     O 

< 

PQ  Pm 

|M 

03 
bD 


e  3 

Cm  P3 


3 
P3 


c8 

O    r2 

r"     03 

E    3 
03    03 

uu 


ca 

s  .S 

CD   m3   r3 


ri5        CO 


03 
O 


^  Pm 
E     03 

o 


mD 

3 


ca 

•i-H 

■a 
> 

co 

O 

m3 

O 

CD 
N 


lM 

03 

E 

3 

CD 


3  03 
Cm  3 
CD     O 


u 

o 

cS 
> 

Q  .  03 

Sco 

bJD^M 


UUUUUUU       QQPSWWW 


O 


cm  co  -^  io 


CD  t-  00  C5 


i— I  CM 


CO  "*  IO  CD  N  CO  05 


O  ^H 
CM  CM 


CM  CO  Tf 
CM  CM  CM 


412 


co 

EQ 

O 

PL, 

0) 

« 

s 


o 
Z 


o 
o 


CO 


-O. 

,fi 

H 

0) 

03 

cS 

cB 

«! 

> 

> 

3 

cS 

03 

w 

c/3 

G 

CO 

CO 

CO 

3 

s 

U 

bC 

bO 

«5 

ea 

i— 1 

O 

o 

^ 

Z 

Z 

G5 
i— < 

<0 
03 
| 

W 


co 
to 

02 


hi 

CO 

£ 
co 
> 
o 

Z 


a>  2 


CO 

■"3    ^ 

-5    > 


o 

0-, 


1-1 

a, 

ca  _£* 

o  "35 


1/5    ~    D-. 

c    ^ 

Zco  ? 


O 

o 


o        ~ 


2 
,3 


3 

G 

-. 

4-> 

o  ^ 

c 

"««« 

T3        5-5 


-5  -r        ° 


•y.  CC 


O 

Z 


/  .1- 


c 

as 


G5 

co 


o 


c 
o 

-1-1 
03 

c 

•i— I 

£ 
o 

c 

CO 
T3 


C 
03 


s 


R 


6^ 


m 

CD 

i 

o 
in 

4 

e 
-2 
"3d 

c 
w 


PL, 


in 

f 

1 
en 

U 

n 

'.O 

rfi 

Lj 

m 

!h 

c; 

co 

a 

4-J 

03 

r- 

J 

fi 

C 

V 

PC  5 


0) 
S 

C 

o 

0) 
PC 


S5         -2 


C 
03 


-m  c/5 


O 

0 
— 


"o  o  "3 

i-  r-  i- 
•*-»  -M  -M 
03     03     03 

uoo 


CD 
I 


-J-   CD 

3    I 


B 
03 

•— 

o 

O    3 


in 
I 


C/l      ro     ,+j 


u 


ca 
U 

R 
ca 


_c   3   co 


U       UhJ  PC  pl, 


c 

cd 


>, 

"bb 

'o3 
>■ 
<U 
M 

Pm 


&5  « 
co    a 

=?   § 

TD  i — • 
O   -H 

o| 

-K  5 

s  I 

OPL; 


C« 


o 

IH 

Oh 

PL, 
03 


B 


o 


5«  CD 

CD  CO 

I       I 

E  E 

CJ  ju 

O    O 

'3  '3 
R   c 

3     3 


C    C  6? 
03    03  CD 

E  E^ 

o  o    I 

pc  pc  g 

-^-  3  s 
c  c  "5  i 

03     03     03     Jj 

.5  .£  U  b 


B 

c 


o 
B 

03 
-i-' 

co 
o 
E 

3  CO 


co 

I 

3 


c;  in 

I     I 


m 

en 

I 


m 

I 


ej   cu  -ti 


^         s-         W 


3  3  3    p< 

C  O  03    CO 

CO  CO  S   ■= 

u  u  Q   ^ 

__  -_  _c  „ 


3     O     U     ^ 

lass 

^    S    rt    oJ 
PL,  CO  CO  CO 


USU 


E 
o 

PC 


o 

ex 
I 


O-. 

<-  ° 

03    R 

r-    ■.— i 

3  _= 
O 


CO 


E 

03 


5 

3 

3 

CO 


03    3 
3  .2 

'3    fl 

Spq 

Oh  — 


B 


O 


O     W3 

1-     Cv 

03     N 


2  5 


Q     3 


cfl     S 


PQO 


to    O 

O  *3 

r-    -^ 
3    3 

03  ^  .- 

•-    ~  3 


U 
CO 


-3    C 

U  E 

co 

CO 

E 

o 

CO 

*^ 

o 

o 

2 

03 

o 

U 

•w 

3  fe§ 

3 
3 

03  co 

3  C5 

0     1 

CO 

«  £ 

6§ 

>-, 

in 

4-) 

+J   s 

i 

3 

3     0 

i 

CO 

3 

fi 

2^ 

•3  0 

•~H 

3 

R   B 

C 

c  -a 

'E 

CO     Co     3 

Ph  Ph  CO 


T3 
B 

3 
03 


m"     D    O     S 
t~rt' — !    '3  ' — ! 


bfi1 


3  ^3 

o   5 


3  - 

03  . 

E 

co  ; 


03 


I  erg  I 


—  T3 
tt    3 

03    O 


03  ^ 

B°J^ 

3     CO  ^ 


B    03 


03 

■  — < 

a 

o 


T3 

B 

03     CO 


03  — !    fx, 


r2      CO 
Q     C 

Am 


o 

03 

- 


3 
O 
fi 
03 

^0 

co 


03  O 

"C    03    O 

CO     >^   X 


C 
CJ 

o 
o 


o 


in 

CN 


CD  t-  00  CD 
CM  cq  CM  CN 


O 

co 


rHWM^lOCDNMOSOHCqcOli 

cococococococococo^-*-'*-^''* 


in  cd 


t-  cc 


CD  C   i-H  CM 

*<?  m  10  m 


413 


c 

0 

u 


i-H 

w 

<: 


>3 

3 
w 


5 
o 


J 
w 
pc 

H 

o 

E 

X 

o 

v. 

PC 

o 

o 

o 

« 
H 
x 


co  *J 

—  — 
O     O 

Ph  „B 

o 


G 

jg  CO 

P     I 


g^coS 


«  3 

p  'S 

03    c 

_0    rG 


<  c 


^  U 


«   PL,     5 


G  re 


Ph    o  «    .„   5 


c 
o  ■£ 

O      r- 


6S 

i!  co    . 
•5  ON  * 


r-H      M 

G 

bo  ca 

S  '•- 

o   oj 

g  +-1 

5  >-> 

<  -Q 


«  5 
g« 
■Sw 

£   l 

Ph     fi 


2  ~bJD 
•1^ 


p— . 

< 

3 

u. 

o 

&3 

y 

IP 

0 

T« 

1 

o 

K-l 

G 

w 

rrt 

PC 

-t-> 

cd  u 


-OpO 

cfl 

a 

nt 

03 

> 

> 

cd 

c3 

CO 

CO 

01 

11 

IM 

In 

3 

3 

CJD  bfi 

CC  cq 

O 

O 

zz 

co 

■  i— ( 
*H 

o3 

05 
O 


s 

o 

13 

co 
u 

Ph 


CO 
i-H 

I 

P 

15 

G 


I 


O 


-G 
o 


U 

o 
G 


65 

CO 

C5 


co    c« 

.2  .Si 
*o  "o 

<H     (H 
— '    -4H 

0  u 

G 
03 


CO 

CO 

I 


CD 
CD 


CD 
I 


■75    a  — <  ■ — i 


4-»  4-)  CO 


Ph 


fS 

13 

z 

CS 

p 
o 
o 

•— 

D 

,B 

■M 

0) 

Z 

p 

CO 

'A 

in 

G 
03 


D 

Z 


T3 
G 
03 

■-H 

03 
D 

N 

2 


G 
03 


O 
— 

Ph 


H3 
G 
o3 


G 

03    c 

In    G 

D    CO 

-G  r5 

g| 


1 

1 

O 

13 

P-^h" 

c 

O 

r—- 

S 

J 

U 

— 

g 

fl 

— 

c 

c 

^: 

pc 

G     C 


A  >, 


O 


as  •; 


03      r^ 


03 
- 
bC 

o3 
u 

n 


co 

co 

I 

,Fo 

C3 

u 


o 

ZC 


u 

G 


43 

03 


•  l— I 

cS 

> 

03 

<*) 
D 

1        cl 

G  ^H 

3  cd 


o 

o 

o 


K 
Sh 
3 
b/3 


fc9 

CNI 

co 

T— 1 

« 

1 

o 

O 

o 

o 

fH 

hG 

— 

03 

03 

U 

u 

G 

c 

03 

03 

s 

s 

o 

O 

eel 

P5 

'o 

fH 
-*H 

03 

u 

G 
03 

G 
o 

Ph     g 

£i 

I"? 

.so 

G     C 

O    03 

-13    G 

£  5 

Ph   PC 


O 

oo  g 
2  s 

Ph"5 

03    O 

o  X> 

-XJ    03 

O   fB 


T3 
G 
03 

o 

o 


1/3 

G 

03 
cjO 
03 
Ph 


o 

CD 
I    _o 

G  "o 
03  ^G 

^G      ^  in 

Sf    w     03 
lie 


o 

I 


o 

pB 

03 

u 

G 
03 

s 

o 
PC 


u 

PC 

Is 

'o3 

s 


3 
7=  Ph 


i;  >  r;  (h  o  s  -h  ^oc 

O  >  U  — P5  CO  H-I  Ph  io 


D 

G  ,B 

c  -y 

3    3 


CXJ 


G 

G  I 

-ph  CO 

G  H 

§ s 

s « 

CD  O 


c 

1 

- 

^ 

O 

■4-1 

IH 

o 

< 

hG 

01 

o< 

1> 

I 


2    h  *j        43 


hG 

CD    Y. 

I    « 

£   u 

CO     *4j 

5  is 


o 

_iH   cc 


B  Tj  2 

5  ^  I 

3  3  oi 

co  PQ  i-J 


Gh^3    e 

S  -tG  3  rt 
•h  '3  ™  "-2 
.!■  hG  -75    O 


03 
M 

3 


03 

•i-l 

G  <    G 

03   ._     03 


13 

G 
03 


ZOP^Q^P^ptiHH^PkPHpHCOCO 


C3  C 
.3    03 

03  T3 

Ph  3 
CO  CO  CO  CO 


c 

— 

1) 

1) 

13 
D 

PS 

4H 

13 
G 
03 


£1  a 


CO 


in 


in 


CON  00  C75  O  -H  N 
lO  lO  lO  IP  CO  CD  CD 


CO  Tf  1C  CD  1> 

CD  CD  CD  CD   CD 


COCDO  H 
CD  CD  t>  I> 


co  ■* 


414 


1 

en 
en 

O 

eu 

I 

en 

03 

O 

Z 


w 


rt 

s 

e 

o 
s 

0) 

^q 
■M 

s 

Cn 

<a 

o 

IH 
Pi 

l-l 

ID 


in 


o  co 

02  CK 


°  s 

o  o 

'2  S 

c  c 

3     3 
CO  CO 


3 
05 
O 

"So 
B 


tP 


en  6£ 

C3  CO 
P      I 


in 
I 

4)  m 
5   I 

O    to 

tort's 

5*3    o    a 

SOS' 


.3 

o 

3 

,C 

o 

3 


rt 


es 


to 

3 

< 


£  op   q 


n<<  i  rt 


T3 
03 

£ 


03 

rt 


3 

X. 
+-> 

03 
O 


en 

3 
oj 

b/D 
rt 
Ph 


03 

u 

0 

S 

3 

O 

■  — 

br, 

■  — 

03 

03 

_03 

}H 

~Z 

2-2 

rt    rt 

<-M 

o 

o 

'S3 

rt 

CO 

> 

> 

[A 

3 

rt 

5 

rt 

en 

03 

en 

en 

3 

>,  03 

03 

03 

O 

H 

3 

H 

3 

in 

bO  &C 

+-> 

3 

en  « 

en 
rt 

rt 

o  o 
ZZ 

3 


69 

C 


M  O    03 
..  W  *J 

en     ,-     > 

US 

It* 


u 

3 
rt 

£ 
o 

rt 

SI'S 

03   *j    rt 

**C 
3=    c  "3 

>-.  c    5 

c  o  -q 

«SSg 

O  *—     03   J* 


CM 

i— I 

I 

s 

JO 

en 

o 

2 


CO 


SW3 
.2 

03  33 
03   w 

b  g 

3    | 

§  5 

cort 


03 

en 

0 


.as 

.-a  m 
o  'q  i 
s  'S3  x 

Om    o 
rt    C    2 

o^  £ 
rt  <^  co 


tn 
03 


C/3 

rt 

rt       .2 

.   W-l 

CO 

^ 

1      j§ 

N     £  "aS 

«  ^«  ° 

T3 

d 

5  ^  to  g  S 

03 

So 

3    £    bfi 

§  5  °2  '5  £ 

3 

l-C 

03    (U     3 

>    >H    >H 

u-j  od  i>  cd 
t—  t~-  t—  t— 

C5 
t- 

CO 

iH   Ol  CO 
CO  CO  CO 

415 


u 

-c 

£ 

* 

o 

05 

c 

M 

J 

*- 

0) 

•- 

o 

£ 

>> 

bs 

■w 

•M 

u. 

"C 

O 

o 

a 

S 

£ 

c 

e 

es 
C 

C3 

u 

£ 

s 
bfi 

0 

T5 

il* 

09 

- 

u 

a 

;a 

o 

o 

J= 

-w 

0 

C3 

A 

U 

-w 

cS 

s 

U 

« 

M  2 


(1) 

o 

I. 

in 

3J 

-w 

>> 

A 

*- 

V] 

la 

o 

o 

ea 

o 

£ 

■^J 

o 

C3 

^ 

u 

o 

-C 

c 
£ 

U 

0 

a 

Ph 

C3 

a 

'     ■ 

0 

^H 

pel 

, — .. 

£ 

CO 

u   u 


_e    « 


eg 

ea 

U 

> 

a 

9 

A 

i. 

£ 

et 

a 

ir 

PS 

, 

3 

o 

6/) 

ec 

E 
O 


3 
Si 


I 

I— ( 


416 


RELIGIONS:  THEIR  DISTRIBUTION  AND  ROLE  417 

ices,  making  mutual  exchange  difficult.  They  may  be  regarded  as  separate 
units,  particularly  since  the  unifying  bond  of  the  Ecumenical  Movement 
and  the  World  Council  of  Churches  of  Christ  has  not  yet  the  qualities  of 
an  effective  movement  on  an  international  plane.  It  is  therefore  not  yet 
tangible  enough  to  be  considered  a  reality  in  political  geography/' 

Similar  considerations  apply  to  the  Buddhist  "churches"  of  Ceylon, 
Burma,  Thailand,  Laos,  and  Cambodia,  and  their  attempts  to  create  some 
kind  of  international  organization  (cf.  Fig.  12-3,  p.  420). 


THE  ROMAN  CATHOLIC  COMMUNITY 

The  most  impressive  national  religious  grouping  is  that  of  the  Roman 
Catholic  countries  ( Fig.  12-2 ) .  Next  in  size,  but  much  smaller,  is  the  group 
of  Sunnite  Islamic  states.  Table  12-2  summarizes  Table  12-1  in  this  respect. 
This  table  shows  thirty  predominantly  Roman  Catholic  countries.  The 
question  arises  as  to  how  far  these  countries  can  be  prompted  to  common 
political  action  by  their  common  religion.  There  is  no  doubt  that,  despite 
their  common  religion,  grave  disagreement  between  them  may  lead  even 
to  war.  The  small-scale  but  bitter  war  between  Costa  Rica  and  Nicaragua 
in  1955  is  a  recent  instance.  There  are  fewer  instances  of  common  action, 
but  more  important,  there  are  frequent  demonstrations  of  a  common  atti- 
tude toward  world-wide  problems.  It  appears  that  even  in  the  case  of  the 
hierarchical  and  well-organized  Catholic  Church  the  underlying  common 
attitude,  based  on  a  uniform  religious  education,  is  more  important  than 
actual  united  leadership.  This  is  even  more  conspicuous  for  other  much 
more  loosely  organized  religions.  It  is,  however,  this  common  attitude 
which  enables  the  Roman  Catholic  Church  to  mobilize  its  adherents  in 
the  struggle  against  Communism.  In  countries  such  as  Poland,  Hungary, 
and  Czechoslovakia  the  Catholic  Church,  even  though  forced  into  passive 
resistance,  is  the  major  obstacle  to  Communism.  Communism  seemingly 
benefited  from  the  active  phase  of  the  struggle,  as  dramatized  in  the  con- 
finement of  Archbishop  Beran  in  Prague  and  the  trial  of  Cardinal  Mind- 
szenty  in  Budapest.  These  victories  proved  so  costly,  however,  that  open 
persecution  of  Catholics  lessened  after  Stalin's  death.  The  Catholic 
Church  has  maintained  a  strong  position,  thus  preserving  for  these  nations 
some  strongholds  of  spiritual  independence  and  preventing  a  full  victory 
for  Communist  totalitarian  ideology.  This  would  not  have  been  possible 
without  the  moral  backing  of  the  entire  Catholic  world.  In  many  states 

6  See  pp.  421  ff. 


z 

p 

o 
u 


i—i 

W 

- 
03 
< 


w 

- 

S3 

z 


cs 
w 
- 
(J 

< 

X 
o 


o 


.2  3 

O   M 

U  W 


o  2 
x  be 

Si 


IS  =* 

Is 


^a 

fi  a, 
co 


a   ce 

03    bB 


O 


>  3  b 

-5  qT'o  -g 


pq 


ec  5 


0) 

a 
a, 

O    P-, 

13 


a  .x  .„~  pl< 
■3  a  '■" 
wj-a  '3   3 

3  U  -a  «  -r 

^  *  §  a  8 


■Sec 


CD    _ 


03 

-   «'   C 
<D    c    ffi 

a  « 


j2 
5 


^Z 


O    13 


^: 


m? 


scs 


£  w 

o      - 

~  .2 
o  -a 


WD  «    E3    CT3    13    « 

>-,    o    in    cs    e    N    3 

<    U    fa    &H      rtU    < 


co  co 


Ph 
CO 
CO 


PC 

ctf 

•i-H 

5- 

PQ 
co 


o 

a 

0) 


•4-' 
&| 

o 
U 


.2  a 
cv2 

o    i* 

■a  v 

—  *-, 

fa  ,0 
co 

«   <u 

-a  PL, 


o  S 


a 

03 
M    03 

*     = 

^2  CO 

—    o   g 

a)       ,2 
o  a  "C 

i— ,    o    o 

a  D 

o3 

a  ^2 
s  a 
13    rt 

03 


a 

O  J5 

oi 

03 

— ' 
^00 

2 

T3  > 

OS  ^ 

OS 

03        ' 

Ph 

.2 

a" 

^3 

iltan 
Arab 

13 

a 

o 

-a 


** 


co  — , 
a 

g  CO 
O  „ 
o  -^ 

o  8 

s* 

*^       (H 

03 

^O    03 

^    ioQ; 


a 

Si 

03 


0 

a 


03 


a 

03 
°e3 

-a 
H 


o 

03 
1-1 


T3 

03 


O 
O 
•-CO 

^^  a 


U  a 


■* 


03     ? 

^CO 

M  5 

lH  ^5 

a  3 
a  T3 

Q2 


O  S 

^2     oi 

S  to 

CO^j 
^-'    13 

os  -t; 

>  J 

J2  ^ 

CO    " 

O  H3 

bo  a 


«    13 
13     ^ 


.  3  a 

a,H  i3  c 

_,  to  5 

^—  £  — 

rt    03  U   iJ 

2".2^-r;':a 
rn  w  "a;  >^-3 

J1N 


to 


■S  M  co  a  ^ 
g  a  -  g 


a 

13 

u 

oj"^. 

t3  -a 
°  S 

r<     03 

a  I-, 

03  J3 

U   o 


03 


oz 


^1  ^l-s 

<  co  ,±i  2  _a 


-s  =n  a  2 

on  -5    H    a 


rt« 


M  a 

a  oi 

P5  J 


- 

13 


03 
03 

>-i 

o 

« 

a" 

03 
03 


03 


03 

cS 

Ih 
CO 


.  a 


a  a 
—  a 

oTZ 
a  ± 

■a  ^ 


co  co  ci  01 


CD 


CO 


tc 

£ 

a, 

CO 

la 

a 

'a 

S 

o 

a 

■— 

bO 

s 

P-1 

bO 

s 

03 

a 

o 
U 

4^ 

3 

CO 

O 

>, 

tc 
a 

•  i— i 

oo 
03 

O 

^a 

-O 

r-* 

'C 

00 

o 

N 

o 

.O^ 

_03 

•*    ** 

o3 
U 

T3 

03 

oi 

a 

W5 

o 
o 

03 

)-l 

a 

o 

'ccT 

a 

4-t 
*J-H 

a 

4-* 

03 

00 

(— ' 

oi 

'ST 
S 

N 

a 

H 

s 

^ 

13 

5 

c 

_CJ 

CJO 

o 

P5 

T3 

'3 

^5 

o 
1-1 

4-t 

oi 

*> 

4_» 

'a 

14 

o 

on 
_03 

o 
a 

C3 

majority 
e  majorit 

'ST 

03 

4-» 

W 

a 

C3 
13 

Is 

03 

03 
03 

00 

a 

CS 

•— 
03 

-z 

03 

x  2 
o  H 

a 
a 

CO 

i 

a 
o 

a 

a 
o 

S 

S 

o 
o 

a 

o 
o 

13 
>-. 
O 

a 

Catholic 
lies  in  th 

_a 

GO 
13 

C3 

03 

o 

r- 
O 

O-, 
03 

00 

'oi 

CJ 

_o 

•i-i 
cS 

1)  Luth 

2)  Refo 

3)  Ortln 
churche 

:  countrie 

bO 

_a 
a 

oo" 

o 

CO 

_03 

'o 

o3 

a  h 

a 

1      ' 

a  a 

_03 

4-4 

a 

oo 
_03 

r~ 

u 

oi  a 

-a   ^ 

— 

a 

rt  a 

4-1 

a 

"Cj 

^W 

03 

(b)   Rom 
Anglican  ch 

u   o 
o 

a 

fib 

S-2 

"      00 

a 
a 

o 

13 

4-* 

a 

CJ 

03 

KA        CO 

f-1 

O 

Fh 

_    ^H 

o 

a 

i 

oi 

be 

hodo: 
f  Mo 

u 

oi 

O 

2~ 

•So 

4- > 

o  'a 

o 

_C3 

s 

4-4 

S3 

o 

CJ 

1-4 

03 

O 

s — 

t!   ° 

-C 

N 

• — ■ 

-^  a 

oi 

T3 

^  r-^ 

rt 

O 

O 

a 

CO 

00 

1— , 

a 

P5 

o 

418 


RELIGIONS:   THEIR  DISTRIRUTION  AND  ROLE  419 

with  Catholic  majorities  or  significant  minorities,  Catholic  parties  have 
sprung  up  and  taken  a  strong,  consistent,  anti-Communist  position. 

Another  example  of  the  political  effects  of  a  uniform  Catholic  attitude 
is  the  part  played  by  the  Catholic  forces  in  the  question  of  international- 
ization of  Jerusalem.  The  Papal  policy  was  strongly  in  favor  of  interna- 
tionalization in  order  to  protect  the  many  holy  places  in  this  cradle  of 
religions.  The  vote  of  a  number  of  Latin- American  countries,  apparently 
quite  uninterested  in  the  case  in  any  other  respect,  can  best  be  explained 
by  their  readiness  to  follow  the  wishes  of  the  Vatican.  The  anticlerical 
government  of  Mexico  was  the  only  Latin-American  country  which  in- 
structed its  delegates  to  cast  their  votes  against  internationalization.  Also 
in  respect  to  many  major  questions  of  intra-European  politics,  such  as 
EDC  (European  Defense  Community)  or  the  Schuman  plan  (European 
Coal  and  Steel  Community ) ,  the  ( Catholic )  Christian  Democratic  parties 
in  France,  Germany,  Italy,  and  Belgium  developed  essentially  correspond- 
ing attitudes. 

The  attitude  of  the  Catholic  Church  in  the  Spanish  Civil  War  has  been 
debated  heatedly.  There  is  little  doubt  that  the  volunteers  on  the  side  of 
Franco— as  distinguished  from  the  German  and  Italian  contingents  sent  to 
Spain  by  Hitler  and  Mussolini— were  almost  exclusively  Catholic,  and  that 
they  were  able  to  influence  the  course  of  politics  in  several  countries. 
Mexico,  on  the  other  hand,  ruled  by  a  nominally  Catholic  government  but 
one  involved  in  a  power  struggle  with  its  native  hierarchy,  gave  active 
support  to  the  Loyalist  ( anti-Franco )  side. 

This  attitude  of  the  Mexican  government  brings  into  focus  the  fact  that 
not  all  nominally  Catholic  nations  necessarily  follow  Catholic  political 
leadership.  In  Mexico,  the  policy  of  the  government,  backed  by  wide 
circles  of  the  population,  has  placed  the  country  among  the  anti-Catholic 
Powers.  Nevertheless,  Catholicism  is  still  influential.  When  Protestant 
missionary  activity  became  intensive,  Mexican  governments  risked  conflict 
both  with  the  United  States  and  Great  Britain  in  order  to  combat  it. 

In  France  the  state  has  been  involved  in  a  struggle  with  the  Catholic 
Church  since  the  turn  of  the  century.  Laws  against  ecclesiastic  orders 
were  issued  and  enforced;  the  separation  of  Church  and  State  became 
a  fact.  Children  were  not  required  to  have  religious  instruction.  Diplo- 
matic relations  with  the  Vatican  were  severed.  At  the  same  time,  however, 
the  French  government  in  the  Near  East  and  Africa  subsidized  Catholic 
orders  and  schools  and  followed  a  course  designed  to  identify  Christianity 
(meaning  Catholicism)  and  France  in  the  minds  of  the  natives.  France's 


S  .2 

"O      CB 

3  .S 


T3 


ER   "£" 

.3  « 


.W 


a -a 

2  § 


IX 


s 


s 

in 

'— -  -C  T3 

-°  2    3 
•^13  i— i 

.„  S  -— 

a)  W  k 
0>  -^ 

-C  — 

2* 

3 

r^  ■"  s 

^    4i  "U 
5  «  S3 

J3    3 

S   u  «o 

-c      -^ 

U    3    - 

«      »" 

c    s-    £ 
A  -3    3 

«u  S 

§£    ° 

a  o-g 

2  n  * 

•5—3 
o         » 

1/5  s 
-c  .2  > 

3  C    >* 

3    -£     - 

e   ?   B 


fi  5 

4-»       O 


O    3 


<N 


0 

ii 

H 

3 
C 

3 
3 

-w 

O 

3 

u 

.Q 

H 

3 

vi 

rt 

4-* 

Q 

•M 

. 

0 

r^ 

s- 

o\ 

Pm 

i-h 

^^ 

F— 1 

u 

— ' 

Si- 

420 


RELIGIONS:  THEIR  DISTRIBUTION  AND  ROLE  421 

protectorate  over  Syria  and  Lebanon  rested  largely  on  conditions  derived 
from  France's  protective  position  toward  the  Catholic  Church. 

All  these  examples  point  to  the  complex  nature  of  the  problem  of  reli- 
gion as  a  motivating  force  in  present-day  politics.  There  is  no  doubt  that 
Catholicism  is  such  a  force,  but  it  is  not  a  uniform  force  and  its  impact  is 
changing  from  country  to  country.  It  is  a  function  of  political  geography 
to  study  the  distribution  of  Catholic  Churches  over  the  world.  How 
strongly  and  under  what  conditions  they  are  influential  must  be  examined 
in  each  individual  case  in  order  to  arrive  at  a  true  picture. 

THE  PROTESTANT  COMMUNITY 

If  the  Catholic  Church,  in  spite  of  its  unique  and  imposing  unity,  con- 
fronts us  with  difficult  problems  in  the  task  of  measuring  the  geographical 
distribution  of  its  churches  and  of  the  part  played  by  Catholicism  in  the 
realm  of  political  geography,  we  find  these  problems  multiplied  if  we 
attempt  to  probe  the  role  of  Protestantism  (Fig.  12-3).  We  have  already 
pointed  out  the  complexity  of  the  mosaic  of  Protestant  denominations  in 
the  United  States,  with  252  Protestant  churches,  of  which  a  nucleus  of  28 
major  churches  remains  if  we  discount  the  smaller  churches  and  sects.  The 
American  picture  reflects  the  complexity  of  the  world-wide  situation  of 
Protestantism.  One  must  be  cognizant  of  the  major  distinctions  and  cleav- 
ages between  Protestant  churches  if  one  attempts  to  draw  conclusions 
about  binding  or  separating  factors  in  the  political  field,  both  within  a 
nation  and  internationally.  In  this  broad  discussion  of  religious  factors, 
we  cannot  try  to  describe  the  large  number  of  churches  which  have  come 
into  existence  since  the  Reformation.  The  Reformation  heralded  a  new 
age  in  which  the  nation-state  and  its  specific  culture  emerged  and  became 
a  cultural  and  political  unit  in  its  own  right.  The  Protestant  churches  draw 
their  distinctions  not  only  from  religious  and  philosophical  roots  but 
equally  from  this  fact.  The  individual  churches  which  were  state  churches 
in  the  Protestant  countries  adopted  specific  national,  dynastic,  ethnic,  and 
linguistic  characteristics  that  in  turn  contributed  to  the  growth  of  the 
evolving  nation-states.  All  this  led  to  the  rise  of  separate  and  competing 
national  cultures  and  militated  against  a  cultural  and  political  unity  of 
the  West.  For  our  purpose,  the  realization  of  this  schism  is  necessary  to 
avoid  sweeping  generalizations  and  faulty  conclusions  based  on  the  com- 
parison of  areas  and  countries  with  "Protestant"  populations.  If  we  try  to 
detect  Protestant  binding  or  separating  elements  within  and  between  na- 
tions, we  must  be  aware  that  in  the  northern  parts  of  Germany  and 


422  HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 

throughout  the  Scandinavian  countries  the  Lutheran  churches  prevail, 
that  in  the  Netherlands,  Scotland,  Switzerland,  and  Hungary,  the  Re- 
formed or  Presbyterian  churches  dominate,  and  that  in  England  we  ob- 
serve an  altogether  different  course  of  the  Reformation  leading  to  the 
formation  of  the  Anglican  Church.  The  separating  factors  are  aggravated 
by  differences  of  language. 

While  it  is  thus  imperative  to  observe  the  distinguishing  factors  between 
the  various  Protestant  churches  in  their  geographical  setting,  we  must  not 
lose  sight  of  the  fact  that  the  political  geography  of  Protestantism  in  our 
time  displays  some  centrifugal  tendencies  toward  international  reconcili- 
ation and  world-wide  Christian  fellowship.  There  is  a  growing  feeling 
throughout  the  Protestant  world  that  a  reversal  of  the  long  historical 
trend  toward  separation  and  division  is  now  under  way,  that  there  is  a 
drawing-together  of  the  bonds  of  Christian  fellowship.  The  Ecumenical 
Movement,  a  child  of  the  twentieth  century  since  it  began  in  a  World 
Missionary  Conference  in  Edinburgh  in  1910,  has  grown  greatly  in  impact 
as  the  result  of  the  tragic  lessons  taught  by  two  world  wars.  Its  last  Con- 
ference, in  the  fall  of  1954,  at  Evanston,  Illinois,  was  marked  by  the  par- 
ticipation of  the  Eastern  Orthodox  Churches.  The  hope  has  been  ex- 
pressed that  this  may  be  regarded  as  the  first  step  in  the  eventual 
construction  of  a  bridge  to  Russia. 

In  comparison  with  the  unity  and  strength  displayed  by  the  world-wide 
organization  of  the  Catholic  Church,  world  Protestantism  as  represented 
by  the  Ecumenical  Movement  is  still  in  the  formative  state,  its  member- 
ship incomplete  and  divided  on  certain  questions  of  dogma.  Above  all,  it 
is  still  largely  a  top-level  movement  which  as  yet  finds  no  effective  parallel 
among  individual  congregations  or  at  the  grass-roots  level.7  On  the  other 
hand,  there  are  signs  of  a  lessening  of  denominationalism  in  the  United 
States,  especially  in  rural  areas  which  cannot  support  several  churches  in 
one  community.  In  Europe,  the  common  experience  of  churches  of  all 
denominations  in  their  struggle,  during  the  Third  Reich,  against  Nazi 
paganism  and  later  against  Communist  oppression,  has  served  to  over- 
come differences  which  in  the  light  of  common  vital  issues  had  lost  their 
meaning.  Yet  a  realistic  appraisal  of  the  present  situation  leads  to  the 
conclusion  that  Protestantism  still  remains  closely  identified  with  the  cul- 
ture of  northern  and  western  Europe,  and  that  the  Ecumenical  Movement, 
while  a  hopeful  beginning,  is  not  yet  a  strong  force  in  world  affairs.8 

7  N.  V.  Hope,  One  Christ,  One  World,  One  Church;  Publication  No.  37  of  the 
Church  Historical  Society. 

8  A.  C.  Murdaugh,  A  Geographical  Summary  of  Protestantism  and  the  Ecumenical 
Movement.  Unpublished  paper. 


RELIGIONS:  THEIR  DISTRIBUTION  AND  ROLE  423 

The  conclusion  at  which  we  arrived  upon  viewing  the  Catholic  Church 
as  a  motivating  force  in  politics  is  equally  valid  in  regard  to  Protestantism, 
even  though  the  Protestant  churches  have  no  international  organization 
comparable  to  that  of  the  Catholic  Church.  The  student  of  political 
geography  cannot  avoid  tracing  the  distribution  of  Protestant  churches 
throughout  the  world  in  order  to  detect  the  extent  of  binding  and  sepa- 
rating elements.  He  will  have  to  observe  closely  the  distinguishing  factors 
between  its  member  churches,  despite  the  fact  that  most  of  them  have 
found  a  common  basis  in  the  ideals  and  hopes  of  the  Ecumenical  Move- 
ment. 

THE  WORLD  OF  ISLAM 

The  Islamic  nations  ( Fig.  12-4 )  have  no  international  organization  and 
are  in  this  respect  comparable  to  Judaism,  Buddhism,  and  to  some  extent 
Protestantism.  The  Khalifat  disappeared  in  the  aftermath  of  World  War  I. 
The  great  pilgrims'  meetings  at  Mecca  and  Medina  from  all  over  the  Is- 
lamic world  are  no  doubt  an  important  factor  in  strengthening  community 
feelings  and  interests.9  However,  the  leading  statesmen  of  the  Islamic 
world  rarely  meet  on  such  occasions.  Nevertheless  it  is  a  fact  that  common 
attitudes  on  a  variety  of  different  problems  exist  among  many  Islamic 
countries  and  are  a  strong  political  reality.  Good  authorities  still  consider 
valid  General  Lyautey's  famous  saying  that  "the  Moslem  World  is  like  a 
resonant  box.  The  faintest  sound  in  one  corner  of  the  box  reverberates 
through  the  whole  of  it." 

Despite  all  this,  the  Islamic  world  is  changing  rapidly,  and  these  obser- 
vations may  soon  lose  significance.  In  some  respects  Islam  is  still  an  ag- 
glomerate of  states  like  the  Christian  states  at  the  time  of  the  Crusades, 
and  can  be  moved  by  an  appeal  to  common  Islamic  sentiment.  In  many 
other  respects  a  transformation  to  the  forms  of  modern  Western  national 
states  is  progressing  rapidly.  In  Turkey  this  process  is  practically  complete 
and  the  residual  Islamic  consciousness  seems  to  be  on  a  level  with  that  of 
Christian  forces  in  Protestant  Western  Europe.  When  Communism  chal- 
lenged the  very  existence  of  religion  in  Turkestan  and  other  Islamic  areas, 
the  Mohammedan  world  hardly  stirred.  This  passive  attitude  can  be  ex- 
plained in  part  by  the  cutting  off  of  the  pilgrimage  to  Mecca  and  the 
resulting  loss  of  contact.  Only  gradually,  and  nowhere  completely,  Islamic 
nations  are  awakening  to  the  Communist  danger.  Religious-national  par- 
ties in  Egypt,  Iran,  and  Morocco  have  occasionally  allied  themselves  with 
local  Communist  parties.  The  revolt  of  the  Dungan— the  Moslems  of  Chi- 

9  See  Bowman,  op.  cit.,  p.  54. 


(M 


on 


o 
a 


a 

£ 


s 

OS 

y 

'2 

M 

c£ 

T3 
& 
es 


o 


01 

hi 
•4-* 

c 

3 
O 

U 

"T 
i—t 
u 


424 


RELIGIONS:  THEIR  DISTRIBUTION  AND  ROLE  425 

nese  Kansu  and  Sinkiang— against  the  Communist  regime  remained  prac- 
tically unknown  in  the  rest  of  the  Islamic  world  and  was  not  supported  by 
it.  On  the  other  hand,  Pakistan  owes  much  of  its  success  in  its  struggle  for 
a  separate  existence  to  the  moral  support  of  its  cause  throughout  the  inde- 
pendent Moslem  states.  British  diplomacy,  recognizing  the  latent  force  of 
Islam,  was  ready  to  give  its  indispensable  help  to  the  cause  of  Pakistan 
because  the  British  knew  that  by  backing  a  Hindu-dominated  unified 
India  they  would  endanger  their  position  in  the  entire  Moslem  world  from 
Afghanistan  to  Libya. 

This  estimate  of  Islam  by  British  statesmen  has  been  confirmed  by  So- 
viet policy  in  Central  Asia  where,  since  1954,  the  U.S.S.R.  has  followed 
a  new  course  in  its  attitude  toward  the  Mohammedans.  For  many  years 
the  Soviet  Union  wooed  the  Islamic  countries  in  the  Near  East,  especially 
the  countries  of  the  Arab  League,  and  at  the  same  time  soft-pedaled  its 
attack  on  religion  in  its  own  Islamic  territories.  It  even  permitted  partici- 
pation in  the  pilgrimage  to  Mecca.  But  the  Islamic  population,  in  spite 
of  their  growing  indisposition  toward  the  West,  did  not  yield  to  Soviet 
propaganda.  The  Soviets  then  abandoned  this  approach  and  resumed 
their  anti-religious,  and  especially  anti-Islamic,  propaganda  struggle  in 
Turkestan,  thereby  reorganizing  Islam  as  a  living  force  in  the  struggle  for 
ideological  and  political  domination.  Late  in  1955,  a  new  policy  toward 
the  Islamic  nations  appeared  to  be  in  the  making  when  Egypt  was  offered 
planes  and  weapons  by  the  Soviet  bloc.  To  try  to  evaluate  the  new  course 
at  the  time  these  lines  are  written  would  be  premature. 

It  would  be  a  fallacy  to  overestimate  the  power  of  Islam  in  its  influence 
on  political  action.  The  lack  of  an  organized  church  comparable  to  the 
Roman  Catholic  Church  is  a  significant  negative  factor  and  the  symbolism 
to  Mecca  in  comparison  with  Rome  is  but  a  weak  substitute.  On  the  other 
hand,  common  religious  sentiment  may  prompt  the  Islamic  countries  to 
parallel  action  or  attitude.  Another  unifying  factor  is  the  close  interrela- 
tionship of  religion  and  law  in  Islam.10  Because  the  canon  law  of  Islam, 
the  Sharia,  is  the  basis  of  the  legal  system  of  all  of  the  Islamic  states;  with 
the  exception  of  Turkey,  the  boundaries  between  these  states  lose  a  little 
of  its  divisive  value  as  compared  with  other  international  boundaries.11 

10  A.  T.  Gibbs,  Mohammedanism  (Oxford,  1949).  Every  human  activity  has  its 
legal  aspects;  therefore,  an  abatement  of  religious  zeal  and  conviction  must  not  lead 
to  a  comparable  diminution  of  Islam  as  a  legal  and  social  bond. 

11  R.  Montague,  "Modern  Nations  and  Islam,"  Foreign  Affairs,  Vol.  30  (1952), 
p.  581. 


a  .a 

C   *j 

3  a 

1/3    o 

n  S 

M  S 

a  « 

13      5B 

3  M 

c  ^ 

3    ° 

O  73 

u  a 

»    - 

z  * 

-C.JJ 

U 

S  8 
B1 

5  i— i 

•si 

O 

*^   u 

a  c 

C  3 
3  O 
3    U 

"a 

o 

ffS 

.2  m 

CS   ■ — • 

»  ..s 

3    fc« 

»  .-3 
cS    u 

-a  .o 

.2  £ 

4-* 


w   3 


•2    § 
3    M 


S  » 

eg  .3 

"3  "3 

~  5 
x?  g 

•   o 

fa 


426 


RELIGIONS:  THEIR  DISTRIRUTION  AND  ROLE  427 

THE  RELIGIOUS  FACTOR  AND  THE  GREAT  POWERS 

Comparable  to  the  geographical  distribution  of  Catholicism,  and  to 
some  extent  Protestantism,  that  of  Sunnitic  Islam  over  certain  parts  of  the 
world  evolves  as  a  primary  factor  of  the  political  map  ( Fig.  12-5 ) .  How- 
ever, none  of  the  contemporary  great  Powers  can  be  classified  as  either 
Roman  Catholic,  or  Protestant,  or  Islamic.  This  reservation  applies  to  the 
United  States,  the  United  Kingdom  and  the  British  Commonwealth  of 
Nations,  and,  in  regard  to  the  Russian  Orthodox  Church,  to  the  Soviet 
Union.  Neither  does  such  identification  of  religious  distribution  and  state 
power  exist  in  China.  Even  though  the  Catholic  or  Protestant  or  the  Sun- 
nitic Islamic  countries,  if  we  would  contemplate  them  as  units,  cover  an 
area  and  have  populations  comparable  to  those  of  the  Great  Powers,  their 
political  structure  and  influence  is  not  on  a  comparable  plane.  In  the  pres- 
ent phase  of  history,  as  cementing  factors  in  the  process  of  binding  nations 
together,  religious  ideologies,  even  where  they  are  strongest,  are  of  much 
less  force  than  are  other,  nonreligious,  influences. 

All  of  the  Great  Powers,  within  their  boundaries,  have  significant  reli- 
gious minorities :  the  United  States  has  a  strong  Catholic  minority,  as  does 
the  United  Kingdom  and  the  English-speaking  member  nations  of  its 
Commonwealth.  China  has  an  important  Mohammedan  minority,  and  the 
same  is  true  in  regard  to  the  Soviet  Union.  Among  the  lesser  powers, 
France  and  India  have  strong  Mohammedan  groups  within  their  borders. 
With  the  exception  of  the  Soviet  state,  all  these  powers  have  been  careful 
in  their  recent  history  not  to  hurt,  by  their  foreign  policies,  the  religious 
feelings  of  their  religious  minorities. 

Both  France  and  India  stress  the  secular  character  of  their  states  and 
the  Soviet  Union  goes  even  farther  in  emphasizing  its  antireligious  phi- 
losophy. Among  the  other  great  powers,  especially  those  with  predomi- 
nantly Protestant  populations,  the  fact  that  their  map  of  religions  discloses 
a  checkerboard  of  many  different  faiths  or  denominations,  excludes  poli- 
cies dictated  solely  by  the  ideas  or  ideals  of  one  religion  only.  This  does 
not  mean  that  these  nations  are  indifferent  to  the  religious  beliefs  of  their 
majorities.  The  United  States  and  Britain  are  undoubtedly  Christian 
powers,  and  even  if  we  look  at  the  extreme  case  of  the  Soviet  Union,  which 
we  shall  discuss  later,  we  find  that  in  spite  of  its  negative  attitude  toward 
religion  and  the  antireligious  bias  of  its  rulers,  it  has  identified  itself  occa- 
sionally with  the  interests  of  the  Russian  Orthodox  Church. 


428  HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 

RELIGION  AS  A  STATE-BINDING  FORCE 

If  one  looks  for  examples  to  test  the  thesis  that  religion  is  still  a  per- 
sistent political  factor  in  the  life  of  countries  or  nations,  the  multinational 
and  multireligious  countries  which  we  discussed  above  are  of  much  less 
significance  than  are  two  countries  of  relatively  recent  date  which  other- 
wise are  strikingly  dissimilar  in  most  respects:  Pakistan  and  Israel. 
Founded  in  1947  and  1948  respectively,  they  are  delimited  primarily  along 
lines  of  religious  affiliation.  However,  that  is  as  far  as  obvious  similarities 
go.  Each  of  these  two  states  requires  separate  discussion. 

Israel:  A  Secular  State.  The  Jewish  communities  are  organized  on  a 
congregational  basis  and  have  no  common  organizational  bond,  only  a 
common  religious  tradition.  Nevertheless,  the  pressure  of  Jewish  public 
opinion  in  the  United  States  has  visibly  influenced  the  policy  of  the  United 
States  toward  Israeli  independence.  This  is  due  not  only  to  organized 
Zionist  opinion,  but  perhaps  even  more  to  the  genuine  religious  feelings 
of  the  non-Zionist  Jews.  It  is  the  more  remarkable  since  in  Israel  itself  the 
ideology  which  kindled  the  enthusiasm  of  the  fighters  for  this  new  state- 
creation  is  a  movement  of  secularized  and  westernized  Jewry.  It  is  a  na- 
tional ideology  which  is  almost  indistinguishable  from  the  national  ideolo- 
gies of  Western  Europe.  While  this  nationalism  has  its  religious  messianic 
roots,  they  tended  to  be  pushed  into  the  background;  Western  influences 
favored  a  modern  secularized  Zionism  which  recreated  Hebrew  as  a  living 
language  and  fostered  a  fervent  nationalism.  Finally,  with  the  acquisition 
of  a  territory  all  attributes  of  a  modern  national  state  were  attained.  Re- 
ligion played  in  this  process  a  very  minor,  certainly  not  an  activating,  role. 
The  most  orthodox  groups,  fundamentalist  in  the  American  Christian 
terminology,  were  opposed  to  this  modern  concept  of  a  national  state  and 
some  groups  accepted  it  only  after  it  had  come  into  existence.  But  from 
this  moment  religion  started  to  play  a  political  role.  The  "religious"  groups 
became  organized  in  political  parties  and  have  succeeded  in  establishing 
a  set  of  laws  which  reflects  their  convictions.  The  troubled  boundary  be- 
tween Arabs  and  Jews,  though  coincident  with  that  between  religious 
communities,  is  almost  exclusively  a  political,  national,  and  cultural  divi- 
sion. 

Pakistan:  An  Islamic  Nation.  Altogether  different  is  the  story  of  the 
contemporaneous  creation  of  Pakistan.  National  unity  in  its  modern  mean- 
ing never  existed  in  India.  However,  common  historical  experience,  the 
subjection  under  the  British  raj,  molded  India  into  a  state  closely  resem- 
bling many  western  European  nations  before  the  full  emergence  of  mod- 


RELIGIONS:  THEIR  DISTRIBUTION  AND  ROLE  429 

era  nationalism.  This  happened  although  many  cultural  and  linguistic 
differences  existed  and  still  exist  in  India.  Deep  social  and  religious  cleav- 
ages complicate  the  picture,  such  as  that  between  Hindus  and  Moslems. 
This  latter  cleavage  was  strong  enough  to  disrupt  the  emerging  national 
unity,  and  in  the  twenties  the  idea  of  two  separate  states  emerged  and 
took  such  strong  hold  on  the  Moslems  that  finally  no  solution  but  partition 
seemed  possible. 

The  intent  to  make  Urdu  the  state  language  in  Pakistan  and  Hindi  in 
the  Union  of  India  emphasizes  the  linguistic  factors,12  but  the  national 
division  is  essentially  one  of  religious  ideologies.  This  is  the  case  despite 
the  continued  existence  of  minorities  in  both  countries  which  include 
many  million  individuals  of  the  other  faith.  Under  the  influence  of  Gandhi 
and  Nehru,  India  has  refused  to  base  its  existence  on  a  religious  idea. 
There  is  a  Hindu  religious  party,  the  Masabha,  but  it  is  of  relatively  minor 
importance.  Its  influence  on  the  shaping  of  the  Indian  laws  is  much 
weaker  than  is  that  of  the  Israeli  religious  parties.  It  seems  more  success- 
ful in  promoting  reactionary  and  nationalistic,  rather  than  distinctly  reli- 
gious points  of  its  program.  On  the  other  hand,  Pakistan  was  based  from 
its  very  origin  on  the  spiritual  power  and  the  community  of  Islam.  Koranic 
law  is  at  the  basis  of  all  its  institutions.  As  in  India,  we  observe  in  Pakistan 
a  struggle  between  conservative  representatives  of  religious  institutions— 
in  this  case  Islamic— and  people  of  a  more  secular  turn  of  mind.  However, 
the  primary  interest  to  us  is  that  the  foreign  policy  of  Pakistan  is  largely 
dictated  by  the  concept  that  it  is  an  Islamic  state.  This  concept  determines 
much  of  Pakistan's  policy  toward  India;  it  led  it  into  a  community  of 
political  interests  with  the  Arab  states,  though  it  is  hardly  based  on  a  com- 
munity of  material  interests;  it  has  endangered  its  standing  with  its  allies, 
the  Colombo  Powers— not  only  India,  but  also  Ceylon,  Burma,  and  even 
Islamic  Indonesia;  it  also  has  helped  to  smooth  out  the  inherited,  danger- 
ous conflicts  with  Afghanistan.  While  in  all  these  international  relations 
Islamic  religious  motives  influenced  Pakistan's  attitude,  there  is  one  in- 
stance of  Pakistan  having  made  a  vital  political  decision  without  reference 
to  religious  ties.  The  military  agreement  with  Turkey  was  concluded  over 
the  protest  of  the  Islamic  Arab  countries.  Turkey,  actually  a  secular  state, 
is  only  nominally  Islamic. 

Tibet:  A  Vanishing  Theocracy.  It  is  difficult  to  find  another  state  of  the 
same  type  as  Pakistan.  Until  quite  recently  Tibet  was  considered  the  per- 
fect surviving  example  of  a  theocracy— a  state  where  the  deity  not  only 
influenced  politics  but,  through  the  priests,  actually  ruled.  In  the  last 

12  See  pp.  385  ff. 


430  HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 

decade  many  forces  have  been  at  work  to  unseat  the  Buddhist,  or  rather 
Lamaist,  theocracy  of  Tibet.  It  is  still  too  early  to  define  the  outcome  of 
this  strange  struggle,  although  the  chances  appear  to  be  slim  that  the  old 
order  will  survive.  Chinese  control  was  imposed  in  1950,  and  in  the  spring 
of  1954  the  Indian  government  concluded  an  agreement  with  the  Chinese 
Communists  by  which  India  recognized  Chinese  suzerainty  over  Tibet. 
Thereby  India  abandoned  Tibet  to  Communist  pressure  and  influence. 

FEATURES  OF  ISLAM  IN  SAUDI  ARABIA  AND  LIBYA 

The  Arab  states  in  general  have  retained  to  the  present  day  the  char- 
acter of  Islamic  states.  However,  they  present  a  picture  which  is  far  from 
being  uniform.  In  Egypt  earlier,  and  in  the  small  countries  of  southeast- 
ern Arabia  only  quite  recently,  Western  secular  ideas  have  found  expres- 
sion. The  religious  movement  of  the  Wahhabis  in  the  Arabian  desert  was 
a  distinct  reaction  against  the  minimizing  of  religious  concepts  in  life  and 
politics.  Through  the  alliance  with  and  the  conversion  of  the  house  of 
Sa'ud  (rulers  of  Riyadh  in  Central  Arabia),  this  puritanical  Islamic  move- 
ment became  victorious.  The  outstanding  personality  of  the  late  Abdul- 
Aziz  ibn-Sa'ud  enabled  him  to  lead  the  movement  to  power  over  most  of 
the  peninsula,  and  at  the  same  time  to  preserve  its  religious  purity.  He 
succeeded  in  this  despite  the  necessary  use  of  modern  weapons  and  means 
of  communication,  despite  the  establishment  of  American  oil  companies 
on  Saudi  Arabian  soil,  and  despite  the  use  of  Americans  as  engineers,  for 
irrigation  and  agricultural  projects,  and  as  pilots.  However,  wars  to  force 
Wahhabism  on  other  Moslems  have  ceased  and  it  would  be  hard  to  show 
that  Saudi  Arabian  foreign  policy  of  the  recent  past  has  been  dictated  by 
its  special  religious  bias.  While  no  international  conflict  has  tested  whether 
or  not  the  religious  factor  has  remained  a  strong  force  in  Saudi  Arabian 
politics,  modern  secular  ideas  from  the  West  have  undoubtedly  made  an 
impression  on  the  country,  particularly  since  Arabs  have  been  trained  in 
western  technology  by  western  experts.  A  European  authority  on  Arabia, 
H.  St.  J.  R.  Philby,  himself  a  convert  to  Islam,  has  warned  that  the  death 
of  Ibn-Sa'ud  may  make  inevitable  and  bring  to  the  surface  currents  which 
have  little  to  do  with  strict  Wahhabism.13 

A  similar  development  already  has  gone  a  step  farther  in  Libya.  The 
Islamic  sect  of  the  Senussi  was  founded  on  puritanic  principles  similar  to 
those  of  the  Wahhabites.  Hidden  away  in  the  almost  inaccessible  oasis  of 

13  "The  New  Reign  in  Sa'udi  Arabia,"  Foreign  Affairs,  Vol.  32  (April,  1954), 
pp.  453  f. 


RELIGIONS:  THEIR  DISTRIBUTION  AND  ROLE  431 

Kufra,  their  way  of  life  remained  unchanged  until  well  into  the  twentieth 
century.  Their  intransigence  was  strengthened  when  they  became  the 
leaders  and  the  last  stronghold  against  the  Italian  conquerors  of  Libya. 
When  Kufra  fell  to  airplanes  and  tanks  they  continued  the  struggle  from 
Egypt.  Finally,  their  head,  Muhammad  Idris  al-Mahdi  al  Senussi,  returned 
with  English  help  and  became  king  of  an  independent  Libya.  The  exigen- 
cies of  the  thirty-five-year  struggle  and  lately  of  modern  administration 
have  tended  to  transform  the  Senussi  brotherhood  into  a  political  and 
military  organization.14  The  parliament  of  Libya,  though  still  subordinate 
to  the  royal  power,  is  capable  of  influencing  politics  to  a  certain  degree. 
Its  strong  group  of  Tripolitanian  members,  many  of  them  educated  in 
Italian  schools  during  the  colonial  period,  are  unlikely  to  be  influenced  by 
purely  religious  motivations  overriding  other  considerations. 

RELIGION  AS  A  SUPPORT  FOR  MODERN  NATIONALISM 

So  far  we  have  discussed  countries  and  nations  where  religion  supplants 
or  tries  to  supplant  other  motivations,  especially  the  ethnic  or  linguistic 
nationalism  of  the  nineteenth  and  twentieth  century  type.  There  are,  how- 
ever, instances  where  religion  and  ethnic-linguistic  nationalism  have  been 
fused  to  such  a  degree  that  theoretical  separation  can  not  be  undertaken. 
In  this  connection  the  position  of  the  Orthodox  Church  and  of  the  Roman 
Catholic  Church  in  Yugoslavia  deserves  investigation.  The  show  trial  of 
Archbishop,  now  Cardinal,  Stepinac  was  initiated  during  Tito's  Stalinist 
phase  along  lines  parallel  to  those  in  other  satellite  countries.  However,  it 
would  be  an  oversimplification  to  regard  it  solely  as  an  act  in  the  attack 
of  Communism  against  religion.  Croatians  and  Serbs— and  several  smaller 
national  groups— have  fought  for  supremacy  since  the  foundation  of  the 
Yugoslav  state  in  1918,  indeed  since  1848  within  the  Hapsburg  monarchy. 
Croats  and  Serbs  speak  dialects  less  unlike  each  other  than  many  French, 
Italian,  German,  or  English  dialects  are  unlike  their  standard  language. 
The  Serbs,  however,  have  been  Christianized  from  Byzantium,  and  have 
lived  under  the  influence  of  this  civilization,  whether  in  an  independent 
state  or  under  Turkish  rule.  The  Croats  received  Christianity  from  Rome, 
were  culturally  under  Italian  and  German  influence,  and  politically  have 
been  dependent  on  Hungary.  The  national  consciousness  of  both  nations 
awoke  in  the  years  of  the  Napoleonic  wars  under  the  leadership  of  theo- 
logians. The  census-takers  of  the  old  Austro-Hungarian  Empire  refused  to 

14  W.  H.  Lewis  and  R.  Gordon,  "Libya  After  Two  Years  of  Independence,"  Middle 
Eastern  Journal,  Vol.  8  (1954),  pp.  41-53  (esp.  p.  51). 


432  HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 

recognize  separate  languages  and  tabulated  a  Serbo-Croatian  tongue.  The 
difficulty  in  distinguishing  nationality  on  the  basis  of  the  spoken  language 
despite  the  existence  of  a  fervent  Serb  and  Croat  nationalism  accounts  for 
the  identification  of  Roman  Catholics  as  Croats  and  Greek  Orthodox  as 
Serbs.15  Thus  the  accusation  against  Cardinal  Stepinac,  though  obviously 
a  link  in  the  chain  of  the  Communist  fight  against  religion,  relied  heavily 
on  alleged  activities  of  Stepinac  on  behalf  of  the  wartime  fascist  Croat 
government  and  his  alleged  responsibility  for  anti-Serb  atrocities.  This 
signifies  only  one  stage  in  the  long-drawn  struggle  for  the  ascendancy  of 
one  of  the  two  nations  and  religions  in  Yugoslavia.  National  and  religious 
motives  are  inextricably  interwoven. 

This  identification  of  the  Catholic  faith  with  a  nationality  struggling 
for  independence  is  not  an  isolated  occurrence.  The  best  known  case  is 
that  of  the  Irish  people.  Many  speakers  of  the  English  tongue,  among 
them  numerous  families  of  English  descent,  have  become  completely 
identified  with  Irish  nationalism  because  their  ancestors  remained  Catho- 
lics at  the  time  of  the  Reformation.  The  number  of  Celtish  Irishmen  who 
at  that  time  became  Protestant  was  apparently  much  smaller.  These  have 
become  indistinguishable  from  other  English  or  Scotch-descended  groups. 

Not  quite  as  thoroughgoing  is  the  identification  of  the  Reformed 
Church  in  South  Africa  with  the  Afrikaans-speaking  Boer  group  and  of 
the  English-speaking  churches  with  the  English.16  However,  it  is  close 
enough  to  notice  the  influence  of  the  fundamentalist  creed  of  the  Re- 
formed Church  in  the  Biblical  concept  identifying  the  sons  of  Ham  with 
the  Negroes,  including  the  curse  of  Noah  for  this  son  and  his  descendants. 
The  leadership  of  the  parties  advocating  "apartheid"  is  largely  in  the 
hands  of  Reformed  church  ministers.  On  the  other  side,  since  the  days  of 
Livingstone,  British  missionaries  have  been  in  the  forefront  of  the  de- 
fenders of  the  rights  of  the  native.  The  African  natives  are  denomination- 
ally divided.  African  churches,  frequently  called  Ethiopian  or  Zion 
churches,  have  more  and  more  attracted  the  Christianized  natives.  These 
African  churches  are  in  some  cases  Christian  only  with  great  qualifica- 

15  Mohammedan  co-nationals  are  often  simply  referred  to  as  such. 

16  "Out  of  a  total  European  Afrikaans-speaking  group  of  1.12  million,  1.02  million 
belong  to  the  Dutch  Reformed  churches,  whereas  out  of  a  European  English-speaking 
group  of  783,000  only  33,000  are  adherents  of  these  churches.  Religion  .  .  .  deepens 
the  cleavage  .  .  .  between  Afrikaner  and  Briton. 

In  the  Colored  community  the  situation  is  different.  About  nine-tenths  are  Afrikaans- 
speaking,  yet  only  three-tenths  adhere  to  Dutch  Reformed  churches,  and  even  in  rural 
areas  the  so-called  'English-speaking'  churches  claim  large  numbers."  K.  Buchanan 
and  N.  Hurwitz,  "The  'Coloured'  Community  in  the  Union  of  South  Africa,"  Geo- 
graphic Review  ( 1950),  pp.  405-406. 


RELIGIONS:  THEIR  DISTRIBUTION  AND  ROLE  433 

tions,  as  they  preserve  many  primitive  pre-Christian  concepts  and  rites. 
Thus  the  racial-national-cultural  division  becomes  reflected  in  denomina- 
tional allegiance.  At  the  same  time  the  influence  of  religious  leaders  in  the 
political  field  increases.  If  the  nationalist  policy  of  territorial  segregation 
should  succeed,  the  political  map  would  become  similar  to  the  map  of 
denominations. 

While  in  South  Africa  primitive  religions  impress  their  stamp  on  al- 
legedly Christian  churches,  in  East  Africa  the  conflict  between  white 
settlers  and  natives  led  in  at  least  one  instance  to  a  revival  of  primitive 
rituals  as  a  rallying  point  and  a  political  weapon.  Centered  in  the  Kikuyu 
tribe  of  Kenya  numbering  over  1,000,000,  the  fanatical  movement  (Mau 
Mau)  which  started  in  1952  has  been  a  continuing  problem  to  the  British 
authorities  and  has  exerted  its  influence  on  other  tribes,  the  Moru,  Embu, 
and  Kamba,  totaling  well  over  1,000,000.  It  is  too  early  to  define  the  con- 
tours of  what  at  present  is  a  fluctuating,  possibly  expanding  area  of  inse- 
curity in  a  region  of  great  strategic  and  economic  importance  to  Britain's 
position  in  Africa.  Many  elements,  among  them  especially  the  growing 
resentment  of  the  tribes  against  the  apartheid  policy  of  the  white  minority 
( numbering  some  40,000  in  Kenya ) ,  help  to  unify  the  tribal  organizations 
in  their  struggle  against  colonial  rule,  but  the  crude  and  cruel  quasi- 
religious  magic  of  curses  and  charms  must  be  seen  as  the  main  factor  of 
cementation. 

Alongside  these  examples  should  be  mentioned  that  of  Japan  and  its 
state  religion,  Shinto.  This  peculiar  creed,  a  mixture  of  primitive  rituals 
and  modern  concepts,  was  proclaimed  as  the  state  religion  not  to  supplant 
other  religious  forms,  but  to  create  a  unifying  bond  for  all  Japanese  irre- 
spective of  their  private  religion,  including  private  Shinto.17  The  belief  in 
the  direct  descent  of  the  Emperor  from  the  goddess  Ameratsu  has  been 
used  to  strengthen  patriotism,  devotion  to  the  country,  and  to  promote 
willingness  for  military  sacrifice.  After  the  defeat  in  World  War  II,  state 
Shinto  was  officially  abolished  and  the  Emperor  himself  renounced  belief 
in  his  divine  descent.  The  opinions  of  different  authorities  about  the 
actual  hold  of  this  belief  on  the  Japanese  are  far  from  uniform.  While 
some  assert  that  even  before  the  war  state  Shinto  was  only  an  outward 
convention,  others  state  that  it  is  still  a  real  force.  It  seems  clear  that  a 
gradual  revival  of  Shintoism  has  been  attempted  since  its  collapse  in  1945; 
however,  the  chief  stress  is  on  ritual  and  apparently  Shinto  has  not  the 
necessary  vigor  to  influence  political  decisions. 

17  See  D.  G.  Haring,  "Religion,  Magic,  and  Morale,"  in  Japan's  Prospect  (Cam- 
bridge, Mass.,  1946),  pp.  209-59. 


434  HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 

Nevertheless,  a  comparison  with  China  shows  that,  although  certain 
political  attitudes  almost  never  develop  in  a  country  whose  leaders  are 
psychologically  conditioned  by  Confucianism,  Taoism,  and  quietist  sects 
of  Buddhism,  they  occur  quite  naturally  in  a  country  psychologically  con- 
ditioned by  Shintoism  and  Zen-Buddhism. 

RELIGIOUS  INFLUENCES  ON  POLITICAL  ATTITUDES 

It  was  mentioned  before  that  modern  India  was  created  as  a  secular 
state  and  most  of  its  leaders  repudiate  any  religious  basis  for  the  new 
state.  However,  the  Indian  struggle  for  independence  was  led  by  Mohan- 
das Gandhi,  the  Mahatma,  by  means  of  nonviolence  and  nonresistance. 
These  concepts,  like  most  of  Gandhi's  doctrines,  are  deeply  rooted  in 
Hindu  religious  philosophy.  So  also  are  Nehru's  international  diplomatic 
actions  thoroughly  and  subtly  influenced  by  these  Gandhian  doctrines  and 
Hindu  philosophy. 

Like  Gandhi,  Nehru  and  other  Indian  statesmen  can  be  understood 
fully  only  from  their  Hindu  background,  just  as  even  the  most  secularly 
minded  politicians  and  statesmen  of  the  West  are  unconsciously  condi- 
tioned by  their  Christian  upbringing.  These  factors  are  largely  outside  the 
field  of  political  geography  and  only  one  observation  may  be  added  which 
shows  the  interrelationship  of  religious  and  political  motivation.  It  is  the 
conditioning  by  the  great  religions  which  accounts  for  the  effectiveness 
of  certain  political  ideologies  in  certain  regions,  and  only  in  these  regions. 
In  this  form  only  is  religion  a  potent,  though  indirectly  effective  factor  in 
many  countries.  Religion  shapes  attitudes  toward  human  life  and  society, 
and  toward  the  state  as  the  politically  organized  form  of  society.  The 
claim  has  been  made  that  Presbyterianism,  Islam,  and  Confucianism  con- 
dition man  for  democratic  forms  of  government.  It  is  for  the  sociologist 
to  determine  the  validity  of  such  claims.  The  political  geographer  can 
trace  only  in  the  case  of  Presbyterianism  that  all  countries  in  which  this 
denomination  prevails  have  an  old  and  persistent  tradition  of  democracy. 

It  would  be  wrong  to  point  to  the  existence  of  political  parties  with 
denominational  affiliations  as  proof  for  this  conditioning  of  attitudes.  It 
appears  rather  that  the  emergence  of  such  political  parties  is  a  sign  that 
in  a  large  part  of  the  population  and  in  the  government  religion  is  no 
longer  the  self-evident,  almost  unconscious  force  it  once  was.  Religious 
parties  have  emerged  in  Christian,  Islamic,  Hindu  and  Buddhist  countries, 
everywhere  a  sure  sign  of  spreading  secularism.  In  Europe  the  emergence 
of  Christian  social,  mostly  Catholic  parties  followed  in  all  countries  the 


RELIGIONS:  THEIR  DISTRIBUTION  AND  ROLE  435 

rise  of  nineteenth  century  liberalism.  Despite  this  common  origin  and 
common  religious  basis  there  are  great  differences  between  these  parties 
which  point  to  the  fact  that  religion  is  only  one  factor  in  their  make-up. 
Although  religion-conditioned  attitudes  are  universal,  Christianity 
through  its  missions  and  backed  by  the  prestige  of  Europe  in  the  nine- 
teenth century  has  the  unique  distinction  of  pervading  other  religions 
with  its  ethical  concepts.  The  Jewish-Christian  concept  of  moral  superior- 
ity of  monogamy  is  accepted  in  Islamic  and  other  countries  today;  and  so 
are  other  concepts.  The  most  individualistic  religion,  Buddhism,  in  one  of 
its  strongholds— Burma— has  begun  to  follow  the  organization  of  some 
Christian  churches,  and  it  is  reported  that  in  this  new  form  it  may  be 
regarded  as  an  effective  force  against  the  encroachments  of  Communism. 
In  Palestine,  the  precarious  truce  between  Israel  and  Jordan  left  these  two 
countries  without  communication  across  the  boundary.  However,  both 
Mohammedans  and  Jews  are  so  strongly  influenced  by  Christian  ideas  that 
at  Christmas  and  Easter,  Christians  are  able  to  cross  the  truce  line  to 
make  the  pilgrimage  from  the  holy  places  in  Jerusalem  to  Bethlehem. 

POLITICAL  PARTIES  AND  THEIR 
GEOGRAPHICAL  DISTRIBUTION 

After  this  digression,  however  pertinent,  we  may  return  to  more  strictly 
geographical  problems.  In  the  preceding  paragraphs  we  have  referred  re- 
peatedly to  internal  political  problems.  As  an  illustration  of  the  problems 
of  interest  to  political  geography  we  may  ask  whether  and  how  Catholi- 
cism makes  itself  felt  in  the  political  geography  of  the  United  States.  The 
claim  has  often  been  made  1S  that  "Catholics  vote  more  Democratic  than 
Protestants."  Actually  a  study  of  the  so-called  Catholic  vote  shows  that 
in  two  political  shifts— that  of  the  Democratic  victory  in  1932  as  compared 
with  the  Republican  majority  in  1928,  and  that  of  the  Republican  victory 
in  1952  as  compared  with  Roosevelt's  easy  Democratic  victory  in  1944— 
the  nine  states  with  the  largest  Catholic  populations  voted  in  about  the 
same  manner  as  other  states.  These  states  are  Rhode  Island,  which  is  56 
per  cent  Catholic;  Massachusetts,  47  per  cent;  New  Mexico,  38  per  cent; 
New  Hampshire,  35  per  cent;  New  Jersey,  35  per  cent;  Louisiana,  31  per 
cent;  and  New  York,  Vermont,  and  Wisconsin,  each  30  per  cent. 

We  have  mentioned  the  existence  and  importance  of  religious  parties 
in  discussing  the  cases  of  Israel,  Pakistan,  South  Africa,  and  Yugoslavia 
Yugoslavia  is  the  only  country  where,  during  the  time  when  it  still  had 

18  P.  F.  Lazarsfelt  et  al,  The  People's  Choice,  2nd  ed.  (New  York,  1948). 


436  HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 

free  elections  to  a  parliament,  three  parties  competed  for  the  vote  appeal- 
ing to  religious  motives.  The  leading  Croatian  party  could  always  count 
on  the  Catholic  sentiment  of  the  Croatian  peasantry,  especially  in  opposi- 
tion to  the  ruling  Serbian  group,  which  was  Orthodox.  Among  the  Slo- 
venes two  parties  had  existed  since  the  nineteenth  century,  a  liberal  and  a 
clerical  Catholic  party.  The  Moslems  of  Bosnia  had  founded  their  party 
only  because  of  their  position  as  a  minority.  Only  the  Serbian  parties,  in 
composition  completely  Orthodox,  had  no  close  ties  with  any  organized 
religion.  Today  Yugoslavia  is  a  Communist  dictatorship,  but  as  far  as  is 
known  only  the  Orthodox  Church  has  made  its  peace  with  the  Tito  gov- 
ernment. The  old  antagonisms  seem  to  persist,  though  underground  and 
with  different  aims. 

Despite  the  existence  of  several  religious  parties  in  prewar  Yugoslavia, 
this  country  shares  with  other  countries  the  experience  that  religious 
parties  are  generally  the  organs  of  the  religiously-conscious  part  of  the 
population  in  a  predominantly  secular  state.  Such  a  party  may  be  the  or- 
ganization of  a  minority  religion,  but  far  more  characteristic  and  interest- 
ing are  religious  parties  in  countries  which  are  nominally  uniform  in  their 
religion.  The  parties  may  be  Catholic  as  in  Austria,  Italy,  Belgium,  or 
France;  Reformed  Church  as  in  the  Netherlands;  Islamic  as  in  Indonesia 
or  Pakistan;  or  Hindu  as  the  Masabha  in  India.  In  all  these  countries  it  is 
possible  to  map  the  area  where  religions  and  political  leadership  are  iden- 
tical, at  least  ideologically.  Such  maps  are  outwardly  similar  to  the  popu- 
lar maps  showing  results  of  elections.  They  show  also,  however,  that  once 
such  a  religious  party  has  been  organized,  a  surprising  stability  results 
which  no  exclusively  political  group  can  hope  to  achieve.  A  striking  ex- 
ample is  offered  by  Austria.  After  Nazi  conquest,  Nazi  indoctrination,  and 
"liberation"  by  the  Red  Army,  the  elections  gave  to  the  religious  Catholic 
party  almost  exactly  the  same  proportion  of  votes  as  was  the  case  a  dozen 
years  earlier;  the  same  areas  as  before  voted  for  this  party.  In  Germany 
a  similar  phenomenon  can  be  observed,  although  in  that  country  Roman 
Catholicism  was  the  religion  of  a  minority  only.  The  Center  Party  had 
been  the  Catholic  party,  with  its  strongholds  in  Bavaria,  the  Rhinelands, 
Westphalia,  and  Upper  Silesia.  It  was  distinctly  a  regional  and  minority 
party,  nor  did  all  of  the  nominal  Catholics  vote  for  it.  In  the  whole  nation 
Catholics  were  outnumbered  approximately  two  to  one  by  Protestants. 
Two  major  developments  have  basically  changed  this  situation  since  1945. 
The  partition  of  Germany  created  a  predominantly  Protestant  Germany 
in  the  East  and  improved  the  Catholic  position  in  the  West.  In  addition, 
over  9,000,000  Germans  from  countries  behind  the  Iron  Curtain,  emigres 


RELIGIONS:  THEIR  DISTRIBUTION  AND  ROLE  437 

and  expellees,  came  into  the  Federal  Republic,  a  large  number  of  them 
Catholics.  Of  the  total  population,  according  to  the  census  of  1950,  51.1 
per  cent  are  Protestants,  and  45.2  per  cent  Catholics.  However,  the  former 
include  a  much  larger  proportion  of  persons  whose  bond  with  their 
church  is  very  superficial.  This  and  the  internal  migration  has  destroyed 
the  formerly  prevailing  religious  uniformity  of  the  smaller  political  ad- 
ministrative units.  The  re-emerged  religious  party  has  declared  itself  no 
longer  a  Catholic,  but  a  Christian  party,  though  drawing  most  of  its 
support  from  Catholics  and  recruiting  most  of  its  leadership  from  this 
denomination. 

POLITICAL  FACTORS  AND  THEIR  RELIGIOUS  IMPLICATIONS 

This  German  example  leads  us  to  another  basic  question,  namely, 
whether  political  changes  would  affect  the  contemporary  distribution  and 
allegiance  of  religions.  In  the  case  of  Germany  we  have  observed  a  dis- 
tinctive change  in  the  distribution  pattern,  resulting  from  the  political 
changes  since  1945.  It  is  also  generally  accepted  that  we  live  no  longer 
in  a  period  when  the  principle  of  cujus  regio,  ejus  religio  (the  creed  of 
the  ruler  is  the  creed  of  the  land )  is  an  accepted  law.  Though  condemned 
by  a  later  more  secular  and  religiously  tolerant  age,19  this  underlying 
principle  is  still  active.  Enforced  conversion  is  generally  condemned  and 
is  not  practiced  in  democratic  countries.  But  invisible  and  often  uncon- 
scious pressures  are  still  with  us.  These  may  lead  to  gradual  and  volun- 
tary adjustments  of  church  organizations,  if  not  doctrines.  In  the  United 
States  the  effects  of  such  adjustments  to  the  Civil  War  period  can  still  be 
observed.  The  largest  Protestant  churches,  the  Presbyterians,  Baptists,  and 
Methodists  split  into  southern  and  northern  branches  and  this  break  is 
still  not  entirely  healed.  Almost  a  century  earlier,  at  the  time  of  the  Ameri- 
can Revolution,  the  Episcopalian  Church  split  from  the  parent  Anglican 
Church  along  political  lines.  Those  Protestant  churches  which  came  into 
being  as  state  churches,  primarily  the  Lutheran  churches,  have  always 
reflected  political  changes.  Even  the  genuinely  supranational  and  cen- 
trally controlled  Roman  Catholic  Church  could  not  completely  escape 
such  influences.  Transfer  of  territory  by  treaty  or  conquest  has  split  old- 
established  dioceses  and  archdioceses.  In  many  cases  boundaries  of  such 
ecclesiastic  territories  were  adjusted  to  conform  with  new  international 
boundaries,  though  the  Papal  decision  usually  followed  the  political  event 
only  after  some  lapse  of  time. 

19  One  of  the  strongest  condemnations  of  this  doctrine  was  voiced  by  Toynbee, 
who  called  it  a  "monstrously  cynical  formula"  (op.  cit.,  Vol.  IV,  p.  221). 


438  HUMAN  AND  CULTURAL  FACTORS 

Apart  from  these  administrative  adjustments  the  Roman  Catholic 
Church  has  withstood  extremely  well  pressures  to  create  separate  national 
churches.  A  few  such  attempts  have  remained  largely  abortive.  One  of 
the  few  partly  successful  attempts  was  the  creation  of  a  "Catholic" 
Church  in  the  Philippines  by  Bishop  Aglipay  as  a  concomitant  of  the 
awakening  of  national  consciousness  in  the  Islands.  About  10  per  cent  of 
the  population  of  the  Philippines  belong  to  this  church.  Another  instance 
is  the  secession  of  a  national  Czechoslovak  Church  from  the  main  body, 
when  national  feeling  reached  a  high  pitch  at  the  foundation  of  this  state 
in  1918. 

This  example  is  important  for  the  understanding  of  Soviet-sponsored 
attempts  to  create  national  "Catholic"  churches  in  the  satellite  countries 
with  the  help  of  schismatic  priests.  Only  in  Czechoslovakia  have  these 
attempts  met  with  some  success.  The  "Patriotic  Priests  Movement"  has 
become  a  tool  of  Communism,  with  relatively  broad  support  among  the 
lower  clergy  whose  material  needs  can  be  better  served  by  the  Communist 
state  than  by  the  oppressed  Church.  In  another  case,  in  the  Ukraine  and 
Rumania,  the  Communists  succeeded  in  forcing  the  Uniate  or  Greek- 
Catholic  Churches  into  union  with  the  Orthodox  Churches.  These  Uniate 
Churches  had  recognized  the  Pope  as  their  spiritual  head  in  the  fifteenth 
century  but  retained  their  national  or  Greek  liturgy.  In  pre-World  War  II 
years,  they  served  as  national  rallying  points  for  Ukrainians  against  de- 
nationalization attempts  by  Poland  and  Hungary.  Most  Uniate  churches 
were  in  regions  ceded  during  and  after  the  war  to  the  Soviet  Union  by 
Poland  and  Czechoslovakia.  Thus  a  successful  resistance  to  Soviet  pres- 
sure for  the  "return"  to  the  Orthodox  Church  became  very  difficult,  psy- 
chologically and  materially.  It  is  reported  that  all  Uniate  bishops  in 
Rumania  are  imprisoned. 

NONRELIGIOUS  IDEOLOGIES 

In  the  present  age,  far  more  important  than  these  attempts  at  forced 
conversion  is  the  process  of  secularization.  We  have  noted  before  that 
almost  all  denominational  parties,  from  Germany  to  Indonesia,  are  ar- 
raigned not  against  other  denominational  parties,  but  against  secular 
parties.  We  would  convey  a  slanted  picture  if  we  did  not  stress  again  and 
strongly  that  political  activity  in  the  present  age  is  much  more  under  the 
influence  of  other,  secular  ideologies  than  of  religious  ones.  The  propor- 
tion of  persons  who  only  nominally  belong  to  a  church  is  increasing  in 
many  countries.  The  United  States  is  almost  unique  in  that  the  member- 


RELIGIONS:  THEIR  DISTRIBUTION  AND  ROLE  439 

ship  of  all  denominations  has  continuously  increased,  absolutely  and 
proportionally,  in  the  150  years  since  religious  indifference  was  at  its  peak 
at  the  time  of  Jeffersonian  enlightenment. 

Recent  experience  has  shown  that  secular  populations  can  be  won  over 
by  emotionally  presented  ideologies.  In  our  age  these  ideologies,  though 
not  religious  in  nature,  appeal  to  emotions  which  usually  respond  to  the 
religious  approach.  Fascism,  Nazism,  and  especially  Communism,  have 
certain  traits  in  common  with  religion.  Some  of  these  are,  restriction  of 
rational  argument  to  specific  fields,  an  unquestioning  belief  in  a  charis- 
matic leader  and  in  "infallible"  books,  further  development  of  doctrine  by 
a  growing  literature  of  commentaries  which  reinterpret  a  quasi-sacred, 
unchangeable  text.  There  is  also  the  proselytizing  zeal  characteristic  of 
youthful  religions,  and  the  readiness  for  self-sacrifice  in  the  service  of  the 
world  mission.  This  accounts  for  a  crusading  spirit  common  to  some  reli- 
gions and  secular  ideologies.  It  also  explains  the  rapid  and  often  parallel 
changes  of  both  the  political  and  religious  maps  in  recent  decades. 

SUMMARY 

In  conclusion  we  find  that  religion  is  a  factor  which  influences  the  atti- 
tudes and  conditions  the  behavior  of  hundreds  of  millions  of  people.  It 
thereby  influences  strongly  the  political  map,  even  where  religion  as  such 
loses  its  hold— its  conditioning  influence  survives,  or  its  place  is  taken  by 
pseudo-religions.  In  either  case,  the  effect  of  these  changes  finds  expres- 
sion on  the  political  map.  It  is,  therefore,  rewarding  for  the  political  geog- 
rapher to  trace  the  distribution  of  the  major  religions  and  their  organiza- 
tions, and  their  relationship  with  state  secular  organizations.  It  is  also 
rewarding  to  trace  religious  affiliations  across  international  boundaries 
and  to  investigate  their  separating  or  binding  functions.  As  in  all  other 
aspects  of  political  geography,  constant  change  and  fluctuation  is  an  in- 
tegral part  of  the  complex  but  stimulating  picture. 


CHAPTER 


13 


Supplement:   Other  Cultural 

Factors 


LITERACY  AND  ILLITERACY 

The  reader  who  has  followed  our  attempts  at  tracing  politico-geograph- 
ical factors  through  the  medium  of  boundaries— ethnic,  linguistic,  or  reli- 
gious—not necessarily  identical  with  political  boundaries,  will  realize  that 
these  are  by  no  means  exclusive.  Among  other  group-cementing  factors 
of  interest  in  the  study  of  internal  and  external  political  geography  those 
of  literacy  and  illiteracy  deserve  special  mention.  But  their  meaning  is 
relative— the  requirements  of  "literacy"  in  the  ( no  longer )  "little  red  school 
house"  in  the  United  States  differ  from  state  to  state,  and  often  from 
county  to  county,  and  are  difficult  to  compare  with  those  in  other  coun- 
tries. Even  if  one  would  compromise  and  agree  on  common  denominators, 
the  mapping  of  zones  indicating  the  geographical  extent  of  various  de- 
grees of  literacy  versus  the  zones  of  illiteracy  would  be  a  highly  specula- 
tive task.  To  the  extent  that  statistics  on  educational  patterns  permit  such 
mapping,  it  offers  a  helpful  tool  to  the  student  who  tries  to  evaluate,  in 
terms  of  geographical  variations,  the  literacy  achievements  of  groups 
within  nations  and  of  nations  themselves. 

An  interesting  case  study  along  these  lines  was  made  by  Ellsworth 
Huntington  1  who  compared  the  literacy  achievements  of  Iceland  and 

1  Mainsprings  of  Civilization  (New  York,  1945),  p.  127  ff.  See  also  Huntington's 
attempt  to  measure  intellectual  activity  by  checking  the  percentage  of  non-fiction  and 
fiction  reading  in  public  library  circulation,  p.  344  ff. 

440 


SUPPLEMENT:   OTHER  CULTURAL  FACTORS  441 

Newfoundland.  The  two  islands  lie  1,600  miles  apart.  They  are  of  similar 
size,  about  one-third  larger  than  Ireland.  Both  are  thinly  populated,  with 
about  150,000  persons  in  Iceland  and  about  375,000  in  Newfoundland,  in 
contrast  to  about  4,350,000  in  Ireland.  Their  ethnic  composition  is  similar. 
Yet  in  spite  of  these  resemblances  the  islands  differ  amazingly  in  cultural 
achievements.  To  name  only  one  of  Huntington's  comparisons,  "until  re- 
cently, more  than  a  quarter  of  a  million  Newfoundlanders  had  only  a 
single  public  library.  In  Iceland,  the  capital  alone  has  long  had  four. 
There  are  also  four  main  regional  libraries  and  scores  of  local  ones,  some 
of  which  are  centuries  old."  Equally  striking,  and  closely  related  to  the 
differences  in  literacy,  are  the  political  and  economic  contrasts  between 
the  islands. 

This  example  shows  how  important  is  the  consideration  of  intangible 
elements  as  expressed  in  the  vague  terms  literacy  and  illiteracy  in  the  task 
of  appraising  all  pertinent  power  factors  of  states  within  their  physical 
environment.  Such  elements  are  as  significant  in  the  over-all  picture  as 
are  maps  showing  the  distribution  of  agricultural  and  mineral  resources, 
cities,  railroads,  highways,  inland  canals,  airways,  or  the  distribution  of 
automobiles. 

Without  such  appraisal  of  literacy  and  illiteracy  factors,  educational 
facilities,  and  technical  skills,  the  student  of  geography  who  tries  to  ana- 
lyze the  power  factors  and  potentials  of  a  region  or  country  on  the  basis 
of  its  natural  resources  alone  would  arrive  at  a  totally  unrealistic  picture. 
The  growing  opposition  in  underdeveloped  countries  of  Asia  and  Africa 
to  foreign  influence  identified  with  colonialism,  even  where  it  is  construc- 
tive foreign  aid,  underlines  the  necessity  of  appraising  natural  resources 
in  terms  of  the  abilities  of  native  populations  to  utilize  them.  As  an  illus- 
tration, in  the  Uganda  Protectorate  in  British  East  Africa  the  great  Owen 
Falls  Dam  (1954)  on  the  Victoria  Nile  provides  an  exceptional  hydro- 
electric power  potential  in  the  center  of  an  important  cotton-producing 
area.  However,  this  large  power  project  is  part  of  the  Protectorate's  Brit- 
ish administration.  If  one  considers  the  fact  that  Europeans  number  only 
about  3,500  out  of  a  total  population  of  about  5,200,000,  the  question 
arises  as  to  whether  the  native  population  possesses  the  educational  and 
technical  skills  to  utilize  adequately  its  water  resources,  of  which,  as  one 
observer  put  it,  the  country  "offers  a  myriad  of  sites."  2  Professor  Frank 
Debenham,  in  a  study  on  the  water  resources  of  British  East  Africa,  ob- 
served that  "one  has  only  to  think  what  the  Chinese  or  Japanese,  or  even 

2  Africa  South  of  the  Sahara,  by  a  study  Group  of  the  South  African  Institute  of 
International  Affairs  (Cape  Town,  1951),  p.  184. 


442 


SUPPLEMENT:   OTHER  CULTURAL  FACTORS  443 

the  Javanese,  would  do  with  such  a  wealth  of  water  running  past  their 
villages  at  such  useful  gradients.  Those  ingenious  and  industrious  people 
would  have  harnessed  these  streams  to  their  creaking  water  wheels  for 
irrigation  or  for  grinding  meal  or  for  rough  workshop  power,  and  would 
have  terraced  their  hills  for  maximum  production."  3 

Education,  knowledge,  skill,  and  know-how  are  intangible  power  fac- 
tors ranging  alongside  the  tangible  factors  and  are  not  less  important  than 
those.  But  to  specify  and  to  map  them  as  one  would  do  it  in  a  geographi- 
cal study  of  industries  or  resources  is  impossible.  As  a  partial  attempt  at 
a  cartographical  presentation  of  these  intangible  power  factors,  Figures 
13-1  and  2  depict  newspaper  circulation  and  frequency  of  radio  sets  on  a 
world-wide  basis;  a  comparison  of  these  data  permits  conclusions  in  regard 
to  a  number  of  factors  in  the  political  realm  in  the  fields  of  literacy,  polit- 
ical education,  and  internal  and  external  psychological  propaganda. 

LEGAL  SYSTEMS  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

The  geography  of  the  world's  legal  systems  is  a  further  example  of  how 
the  geographical  distribution  of  certain  cohesive  institutions  of  human 
society  demonstrate  binding  or  separating  qualities.  Of  the  innumerable 
factors  which  together  constitute  a  legal  system  there  are  many  which  can 
be  traced  to  the  influence  of  geography.  It  would  lead  too  far  afield  to 
pursue  these  influences.  John  H.  Wigmore  has  undertaken  the  long- 
neglected  task  of  subdividing  the  world  map  into  the  major  legal  systems. 
Those  in  existence  twenty-five  years  ago  were  the  Anglican,  Chinese,  Ger- 
manic, Hindu,  Japanese,  Mohammedan,  Romanic,  Slavic,  and  Soviet.  For 
areas  where  no  legal  system  had  been  developed,  a  color  for  Tribal  Cus- 
tom was  added.4  Redrawn  today,  this  map  would  require  a  number  of 
alterations,  especially  in  the  area  of  Slavic  law  where  the  extension  of  the 
Soviet  orbit  has  carried  with  it  the  expansion  of  Soviet  law.  A  sense  of 
identity  or  similarity  based  on  a  law  system  does  not  promote  as  strongly 
the  belonging-together  concept  as  does  the  ethnic,  linguistic,  and  religious 
community.  However,  just  as  these  elements  express,  within  or  beyond  the 
political  boundaries  of  a  state,  the  cultural  traits  which  serve  as  connecting 
links  between  groups  and  nations,  thus  to  a  lesser  but  also  significant  de- 
gree related  laws,  the  common  adherence  to  principles  of  international 
law,  or  tribal  customs  serve  the  same  purpose.  Contrariwise,  the  line  or 
zone  which  indicates  where,  regardless  of  political  boundaries,  the  basic 

3  Ibid. 

4  "A  Map  of  the  World's  Laws,"  Geographical  Review  (1929),  pp.  114-120. 


o                        o 

1 _           CM                                                                                              .     » 

*&         _— — ■ — — I 

'o 

n^i^  5 

-I         "^ik^^^  • 

if 

X/\--\                 ♦             ^^ 

Ajf 

j^^r^~i^\ 

o  A                 cS*'^- — -'              "^ 

ay    1                               z"* 

(4^~Y^i                     1 

o/\                                                    f 

%4 

ti\'    il^Hi 

^.jj 

;rt 

v-gil 

2    N                       7 

(             y"1 — *3\^ 

i     *        ^ 

^?sG^^  ^* 

°o  '         2                                                                    V  J 

^            (         /J 

1                                                                      ~~"^I  °° 

1                                To 

1           /  J 

\  _^P 

H~n7> 

O     „  /\*                    1 

L    _vJ! 

i 1  r- 

°0  ^                 ** — •**/ 

SJM" 

\  *  ' 

— 1~          _                 ^^  / 

00                                            f 

^ 

IP 

of        ^^  V» 

(5w£k   .,■- 

<o  a                         P--T 

— —  °o 

w                 — /rf — 

y  & 

^4 

Cjfc\W 

t  ~A                    £c^^ 

*^V_-J^ 

y — w-^N          ^J~i—A       '\u*Ji 

<"* 

o        it     .£? : "iii 

rA\    ; 

rr  J/xff*)/         / 

.  o 

CM 

O  J?  t^EC                   ^vr^ 

00        iTi^                     'M* 

1 

o                                                  1 

a 

o  —                                    1 

i 

•• 

**%$ 

°o           **\ , 

(c 

<*\  ■*>>. 

"" O 

— h 

i 

* '                  K\ 

1 

o 

00          Z.                                 T^rt  J^T?      ^-^jTj!|j 

1 

l^r   to 

1 
1 
1 

1 

o   J  -*  )  )  kr~*  ^T     m?  y               \ 

jiK 



<1  /     jX-P_L              V-^g 

fJt 

13r                     o 

\L     *•»,  (*^l_ ->: 

4-— L^H  Jfiff^f  v\    >^^ 

sOirf  /M^(5)1 

1 

1     o 

\    o 

MD  P 

■trr  V^V  **" )  v  ^"  ) 

1 

1 

V,  o 

Kjf* 

1 

l  rh^\- 

^  ^  ©  ^jsJSSgf 

—  "v  1                      ^V(^^^ 

3 

\     3STl©uw 

o               /vt/  3          V\ 

-^     @i'>s1iAt^v<W 

^7            /            ^^^"^-^ 

ji~ — ■ Lz 

>      ,;.-:■.:, 

A— \  /nYta 

1  co  J  l      7&li 

^ 

ivviS? 

*       ■ — ■ — l~ 

°c 

a 

®^®(E 

iSx 

4.44 


SUPPLEMENT:  OTHER  CULTURAL  FACTORS  445 

law  concepts  differ  can  be  indicative  of  separating  factors  which  explain 
characteristics  of  the  internal  and  external  geography  of  states.  Quebec 
and  Louisiana,  where  the  Roman  legal  system  survived,  offer  an  illustra- 
tion on  the  map  of  North  America,  for  the  internal  political  geography  of 
Canada  and  the  United  States.  The  present  struggle  for  survival  of  the 
Romanic-Germanic  law  system  in  the  Eastern  Zone  of  Germany  depicts 
the  crucial  situation  in  that  area.  In  the  Mohammedan  world  we  discover 
an  interesting  cleavage  between  the  laws  of  the  desert  and  those  of  the 
oases,  as  between  Bedouin  law  and  the  Egyptian  Penal  Code.  Thus  the 
political  geography  of  legal  systems  evolves  as  an  additional  aid  in  the 
task  of  appraising  the  cohesive  and  divisive  influences  and  power  factors 
among  the  nations. 


Part 


3 


THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR 
IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 


CHAPTER 


14 


The  Importance  or  Economic 
Factors  in  Political  Geography 


THE  RELATIVE  IMPORTANCE  OF  LOCATION  AND 
OTHER  FACTORS 

When  Halford  J.  Mackinder  read  his  now  famous  paper,  "The  Geo- 
graphical Pivot  of  History"  at  the  Royal  Geographical  Society  on  January 
25,  1904,  he  provoked  some  interesting  and  all-too-brief  comments  from 
his  friend  and  fellow  member,  L.  S.  Amery,  later  First  Lord  of  the  Ad- 
miralty and  Secretary  of  State  for  India.  The  paper,  and  these  comments, 
pose  in  an  interesting  way  the  problem  of  the  significance  of  economic 
factors  in  political  geography.  Mackinder,  it  will  be  recalled,  had  ad- 
vanced the  thesis  that  the  Asiatic  steppe  lands,  whose  horse-riding  no- 
mads had  always  presented  a  threat  to  Europe,  would  in  the  "closed 
system"  of  the  modern  world,  and  with  the  "full  development  of  her 
modern  railway  mobility"  become  "the  pivot  region  of  the  world's  poli- 
tics." Mackinder  obviously  did  not  ignore  economic  and  social  factors  but 
he  concluded  that  in  the  modern  world  they  conferred  a  special  advantage 
on  land  power  as  opposed  to  sea  power.  "Nor  is  it  likely,"  he  predicted, 
"that  any  possible  social  revolution  will  alter  [Russia's]  essential  relations 
to  the  great  geographical  limits  of  her  existence."  x 

1 H.  J.  Mackinder,  "The  Geographical  Pivot  of  History,"  Geographical  Journal 
(April,  1904),  pp.  14-16.  Mackinder's  emphasis  on  "railway  mobility"  is  foreshadowed 
in  the  writings  of  the  German  Friedrich  List  who,  more  than  a  century  ago,  dwelt  on 
the  influence  of  railways  upon  the  shifting  balance  of  military  power.  See  the  im- 
portant study  by  E.  M.  Earle  on  "Adam  Smith,  Alexander  Hamilton,  Friedrich  List: 
The  Economic  Foundations  of  Military  Power,"  in  E.  M.  Earle,  ed.,  Makers  of  Modern 
Strategy  (Princeton,  1943),  pp.  117-155  (148-152). 

449 


450       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

In  his  extemporaneous  remarks  Amery  insisted  that  sea  mobility  was 
still  more  important  to  military  power  than  railway  mobility  and  that 
before  long  both  would  be  supplemented  "by  the  air  as  a  means  of  loco- 
motion." This  train  of  thought  led  him  to  the  concluding  observation  that 
".  .  .  to  look  forward  a  bit ...  a  great  deal  of  this  geographical  distribution 
must  lose  its  importance,  and  the  successful  powers  will  be  those  who 
have  the  greatest  industrial  basis.  It  will  not  matter  whether  they  are  in 
the  center  of  a  continent  or  on  an  island;  those  people  who  have  the  in- 
dustrial power  and  the  power  of  invention  and  of  science  will  be  able  to 
defeat  all  others."  2 

In  retrospect  it  must  be  judged  that  Amery's  views  were  the  more  real- 
istic. The  U.S.S.R.  has  become  a  world  power  not  so  much  because  of  its 
location  in  the  "closed  heartland  of  Euro-Asia"  as  because  of  a  profound 
and  far-reaching  social  revolution  which  made  the  development  of 
Amery's  industrial  power  the  paramount  object  of  policy.  Railways  have, 
indeed,  worked  great  wonders  in  the  steppes  because,  as  Mackinder  cor- 
rectly saw,  "they  directly  replace  horse  and  camel  mobility,  the  road  stage 
of  development  having  been  omitted."  But  their  development  has  been 
slow  and  costly  and  the  vast  distances  of  the  heartland  are  still  a  liability 
rather  than  an  asset. 

The  controversy  between  the  two  men  was  mainly  one  of  emphasis. 
Mackinder  failed  to  foresee  the  advent  of  air  power,  but  he  did  recognize 
in  theory  that  other  factors  play  their  part  as  well  as  the  geographical 
ones: 

1  have  spoken  as  a  geographer.  The  actual  balance  of  political  power  at  any 
given  time  is,  of  course,  the  product,  on  the  one  hand,  of  geographical  condi- 
tions, both  economic  and  strategic,  and,  on  the  other  hand,  of  the  relative 
number,  virility,  equipment,  and  organization  of  the  competing  peoples.  In 
proportion  as  these  quantities  are  accurately  estimated  are  we  likely  to  adjust 
differences  without  the  crude  resort  to  arms.  And  the  geographical  quantities 
in  the  calculation  are  more  measurable  and  more  nearly  constant  than  the 
human.3 

Certainly  once  the  U.S.S.R.  has  acquired  the  power  of  industry  and  sci- 
ence of  which  Amery  spoke,  its  central  location  may  well  prove  of  crucial 
advantage  in  the  outward  extension  of  its  piecemeal  conquests.  The  West 
has  already  learned  how  costly  is  the  task  of  containing  a  powerful  ag- 
gressor at  all  points  around  this  vast  perimeter. 

After  fifty  years  this  exchange  of  views  still  provides  a  needed  reminder 
of  the  desirability  of  that  bridge  between  the  physical  and  social  sciences 

2  Mackinder,  op.  cit.,  p.  21. 

3  Mackinder,  op.  cit.,  p.  17. 


THE  IMPORTANCE  OF  ECONOMIC  FACTORS  451 

that  Mackinder  called  upon  the  geographers  to  build.  And  the  above  quo- 
tation constitutes  good  advice  for  the  student  of  political  geography,  espe- 
cially when  he  addresses  himself,  as  we  do  now,  to  the  problem  of  the  rel- 
ative importance  of  geographical  conditions  on  the  one  hand,  and  of  the 
use  and  adaptations  which  various  peoples  make  of  the  resources  which 
geography  provides.  It  suggests  among  other  things  that  the  service  eco- 
nomic analysis  can  perform  for  political  geography  is  something  more 
than  a  mere  cataloging  of  economic  resources.  Political  geography  re- 
quires more  than  an  understanding  of  economic  geography,  or  of  the 
geographical  conditions  characterized  in  Mackinder's  phrase  as  economic. 
The  analysis  must  also  relate  these  conditions  to  the  "number,  virility, 
equipment  and  organization"  of  states  in  order  to  arrive  at  "the  actual 
balance  of  political  power." 

Of  necessity  any  such  analysis  must  have  a  focus.  The  obvious  factors 
in  any  calculation  of  political  power  relationships  in  today's  world  are  the 
states  which  are  the  centers  of  military  and  political  power,  the  United 
States  and  the  U.S.S.R.,  together  with  their  allies  and  "satellites"  on  both 
sides.  But  if  the  balance  in  today's  world  is  struck  simply  between  these 
two  groups  of  states  opposing  each  other  in  the  "cold  war"  it  would  be 
incomplete  because  it  would  ignore  a  large  group  of  states  hopelessly 
lacking  in  the  economic  and  military  capabilities  for  great  power  status, 
but  which  constitute  a  "bloc"  of  increasing  cohesiveness  and  influence  in 
world  politics.  These  are  the  underdeveloped  states  of  Asia,  Africa,  and 
Latin  America.  By  and  large  these  states  have  accepted  their  lot  as  states 
which  are  virtually  defenseless  against  aggression  from  either  the  Sino- 
Soviet  bloc  or  the  other  great  powers.  They  therefore  do  not  seek  to 
develop  more  military  strength  than  is  needed  to  protect  them  from  their 
smaller  neighbors.  Instead,  they  seek  the  domestic,  political,  and  social 
advantages  that  come  from  economic  progress.  A  large  part  of  their 
bureaucratic  energies  are  devoted  to  government-sponsored  and  directed 
measures  to  speed  up  the  process  of  economic  development.  Many  of  them 
remain  "uncommitted"  politically  because  they  have  not,  as  a  practical 
matter,  been  able  to  choose  between  the  social  and  political  systems  rep- 
resented by  Communism  and  the  democratic  West. 

In  the  conflicting  attitudes  of  states  toward  wealth  and  economic  life 
and  their  relation  to  national  power,  one  can  distinguish,  in  Mackinder's 
term,  three  sets  of  "competing  peoples  "—the  industrialized  states  of 
Europe  and  North  America,  the  Sino-Soviet  bloc,  and  the  underdeveloped 
areas  of  Asia,  Africa,  and  Latin  America.  These  three  groups  of  states  are 
related  by  two  equations  which  are  significant  for  today's  student  of 


452       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

political  geography.  One  represents  the  relationship  between  the  eco- 
nomic power  of  the  Soviet  bloc  and  that  of  the  industrialized  and  anti- 
Communist  West.  The  economic  capabilities  of  both  groups  of  states, 
though  resting  on  radically  different  social  foundations,  are  growing; 
how  do  the  rates  of  growth  compare  and  what  do  they  signify  for  the 
future?  The  other  equation  represents  the  relationship  between  living 
standards  and  rates  of  economic  growth  in  the  industrialized  states  of  the 
West  and  those  of  the  so-called  underdeveloped  countries  outside  the 
Communist  bloc.  Whether  the  gap  between  the  two  can  be  narrowed, 
and  at  what  rate,  may  determine  the  resistance  of  the  underdeveloped 
countries  to  Communist  propaganda  and  subversion,  and  consequently 
their  ultimate  alignment  in  the  struggle  between  Communism  and  the 
democratic  West. 

This  discussion  of  economic  factors  in  political  geography  is  essentially 
an  attempt  to  estimate  the  quantities  in  these  equations  and  their  signifi- 
cance for  the  three  main  political  groupings  of  the  present-day  world.  In 
making  the  attempt  we  shall  try  in  particular  to  show  how  variations  in 
political  and  military  power  among  states  are  related  to  variations  in  their 
underlying  economic  capabilities  and  how  these  capabilities  in  turn  are 
related  to  geographical  factors  such  as  climate,  mineral  resources,  and 
waterways.  In  addition  we  shall  consider  how  the  attempt  to  expand  eco- 
nomic capabilities,  either  for  power  or  welfare  purposes,  influences  the 
attitudes  and  actions  of  the  various  states.  Before  proceeding  to  these 
tasks,  however,  the  remainder  of  this  chapter  sets  forth  certain  fundamen- 
tal principles  concerning  the  relation  between  economic  capabilities  and 
national  power,  and  between  physical  geography  and  economic  growth. 

ECONOMIC  CAPABILITIES  AND  NATIONAL  POWER 

The  ability  of  states  to  afford,  in  the  words  of  Adam  Smith,  "the  great 
expense  of  firearms,"  4  is  nowadays  so  obviously  a  condition  of  national 
power  that  its  analysis  is  essential  to  an  understanding  of  international 
political  relationships.  A  brief  explanation  of  this  concept  of  economic 
capability  seems  desirable  to  avoid  possible  misunderstanding. 

In  the  following  discussion,  attention  is  centered  on  the  concept  of 

4  ...  In  modern  war  the  great  expense  of  firearms  gives  an  evident  advantage  to 
the  nation  which  can  best  afford  that  expense;  and  consequently,  to  an  opulent  and 
civilized,  over  a  poor  and  barbarous  nation.  In  ancient  times,  the  opulent  and  civilized 
found  it  difficult  to  defend  themselves  against  the  poor  and  barbarous  nations.  In 
modern  times  the  poor  and  barbarous  find  it  difficult  to  defend  themselves  against  the 
opulent  and  civilized  (Wealth  of  Nations,  Book  V,  Part  I,  Ch.  1). 


THE  IMPORTANCE  OF  ECONOMIC  FACTORS  453 

economic  capabilities  for  military  power.  It  is,  of  course,  readily  apparent 
that  not  all  conflicting  international  interests  are  resolved  by  resort  to 
war.  A  powerful  modern  state  will  require  and  vise  its  economic  capabili- 
ties in  order  to  advance  its  foreign  policy  by  means  short  of  war,  such  as 
economic  or  military  assistance  to  friendly  nations.  It  is  true  that  economic 
capabilities  are  seldom,  if  ever,  as  fully  mobilized  for  other  purposes  as 
for  the  national  defense  in  time  of  war.  Moreover,  in  the  modern  world, 
the  influence  of  a  national  state  in  international  affairs  depends  ultimately 
on  its  military  capabilities.  Hence,  political  and  strategic  capabilities  are 
essentially  a  function  of  the  economic  capabilities  for  war.  However,  the 
reader  is  asked  to  bear  in  mind  that  the  concept  of  economic  capabilities 
comprehends  other  purposes  than  purely  military  ones. 

Economic  capabilities  for  war  may  be  defined  as  that  portion  of  the 
resources  of  a  state  (usually  measured  by  national  product  or  national 
income)  which  it  can  devote  to  military  purposes.  Since  the  Industrial 
Revolution  the  ability  of  modern  states  to  maximize  their  economic  capa- 
bilities for  war  has  depended  on  their  ability  to  establish  and  maintain 
a  position  of  superiority  in  manufacturing  and  technology,  and  to  extract 
from  the  competing  claims  of  the  various  private  interests  in  the  economy, 
sufficient  resources  for  the  national  defense.  As  states  everywhere  are 
developing  both  abilities,  the  economic  potential  for  war  comes  to  be  in- 
creasingly a  function  of  the  size  (in  terms  of  population  and  resources) 
of  the  national  economy.5 

Mere  economic  development  ( as  indicated  by  the  average  standard  of 
living,  per  capita  incomes,  the  state  of  the  arts,  etc. )  is  an  insufficient  indi- 
cation of  national  power.  Switzerland,  for  example,  has  one  of  the  highest 
average  incomes  per  capita  in  the  world,  much  higher  than  that  of  the 
U.S.S.R.  Yet  the  latter,  not  the  former,  has  the  economic  base  for  the 
massive  power  position  that  the  Soviet  Union  in  fact  enjoys.  Likewise, 
size  by  itself  is  insufficient,  as  the  examples  of  China  and  India  demon- 
strate. What  is  important  is  the  optimum  combination  of  size  and  devel- 
opment, of  aggregate  wealth  or  income,  widely  diversified  as  to  type  of 
commodities  and  services  produced,  and  distributed  in  such  a  manner  as 
to  afford  a  relatively  high  proportion  of  expenditures  on  capital  and  mili- 
tary goods.  Within  fairly  large  limits,  development  has  up  to  now  ordi- 
narily been  the  more  important  of  the  two  factors.  A  smaller  but  devel- 
oped state  with  relatively  high  per  capita  incomes  (the  United  Kingdom 
or  Japan )  will  have  a  surplus  over  and  above  minimum  consumption  and 

5  For  a  discussion  of  this  point  see  E.  Lederer's  chapter  on  "War  Economics"  in 
H.  Speier  and  A.  Kahler,  eds.,  War  in  Our  Time  (New  York,  1939),  pp.  206-220. 


454        THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

investment  requirements,  while  a  very  large  state  with  low  per  capita 
incomes  (like  India  or  China)  may  have  a  much  smaller  surplus  for  mili- 
tary and  strategic  purposes.  When,  however,  such  large  states  come  under 
the  grip  of  totalitarian  governments,  as  in  Communist  China,  the  share 
of  the  national  product  used  for  military  and  security  purpose  can  be 
forcibly  enlarged.  The  military  capabilities  of  such  a  country  may  there- 
fore be  expanded  at  a  much  faster  rate  than  its  over-all  economic  develop- 
ment would  lead  one  to  expect. 

The  acceptance  of  the  economics  of  total  war  not  only  by  the  totalitar- 
ian states  but,  in  theory  at  any  rate,  by  almost  every  advanced  country, 
and  "the  almost  uniform  development  of  modern  technique  in  all  coun- 
tries" G  (of  which  the  rapidity  with  which  the  U.S.S.R.  copied  jet  engine 
and  atomic  weapon  designs  is  a  good  example)  have  made  aggregate  re- 
sources the  most  important  single  factor  in  determining  economic  capa- 
bilities. 

RELATIVE  CAPABILITIES 

The  relative  capability  of  nation  states  has  been  subject  to  constant 
change,  even  before  the  advent  of  total  war.  The  Netherlands  was  once 
the  leading  manufacturing  country  of  Europe,  and  Rotterdam  and  Ant- 
werp were  the  leading  financial  centers  because  of  the  wool  trade.  In 
those  days  Holland  was  a  great  power.  In  the  days  of  the  great  explora- 
tions, Spain  and  Portugal  were  among  the  wealthiest  and  strongest  coun- 
tries in  Europe.  The  pre-eminence  of  these  states  gave  way  to  that  of  the 
United  Kingdom.  Similarly  the  superiority  of  the  United  Kingdom  gave 
way  in  the  twentieth  century  under  the  strain  of  two  World  Wars  and 
especially  with  the  rise  of  the  United  States  and  the  Soviet  Union.  After 
World  War  II,  Great  Rritain,  although  still  a  "big  power"  is  no  longer  a 
first-ranking  power,  and  this  is  due  directly  to  the  relative  decline  in  her 
economic  strength.  A  good  illustration  of  this  is  the  action  of  Great  Britain 
in  1947  in  turning  over  to  the  United  States  her  commitments  in  Greece 
and  asking  the  United  States  to  assume  responsibility  for  stability  in  that 
country.  The  government  of  Great  Britain  knew  that  Greece  needed  large 
measures  of  both  economic  and  military  assistance  that  the  United  King- 
dom could  no  longer  afford  to  give.  This  is  not  to  say  that  the  United 
Kingdom  is  economically  weaker  now  than  in  the  nineteenth  century  or 
than  before  the  second  World  War.  Actually,  total  output  and  exports, 
both  in  value  and  in  physical  volume,  are  larger  than  ever.  But  in  terms 

6  Lederer,  loc.  cit.,  p.  220. 


THE  IMPORTANCE  OF  ECONOMIC  FACTORS  455 

of  the  cost  of  the  growing  responsibilities  and  commitments  of  national 
power,  the  United  Kingdom's  capabilities  are  declining. 

In  the  new  atomic  age,  an  enormous  economic  base  is  required  not  only 
to  produce  atomic  and  other  unconventional  arms  but  to  carry  on  the 
necessary  scientific  research  and  development  to  maintain  superiority. 
Only  three  states  are  known  to  produce  nuclear  weapons  and  of  these  only 
two,  the  United  States  and  the  U.S.S.R.,  can  seriously  be  regarded  as 
first-ranking  powers  (Fig.  14-1).  In  fact,  it  is  the  reduction  of  the  number 
of  great  powers  to  only  these  two  which  characterizes  the  political  and 
strategic  aspect  of  this  new  age.  Both  have  strong  economic  bases  com- 
pounded in  each  case  of  size  (area,  population,  and  resources)  and  of 
development  (industrialization,  high  rates  of  investment,  and  intensive 
application  of  technology  to  industrial  processes ) . 

It  is  not  intended  to  suggest  that  national  power  is  a  simple  function 
of  aggregate  economic  capabilities.  There  are  variations  in  the  social 
limits  within  which  modern  states  can  mobilize  resources  for  military 
purposes.  Totalitarian  states  can  command  a  larger  proportion  of  re- 
sources for  extended  periods  than  can  democracies.  In  this  way  the 
U.S.S.R.  now  presents  a  growing  threat  to  the  peace  of  the  world  although 
its  gross  economic  capabilities  are  less  than  those  of  the  United  States 
alone  and  less  than  those  of  all  Western  European  countries  combined. 
On  the  other  hand,  there  are  tangible  and  intangible  qualities  of  leader- 
ship, of  co-operation,  of  national  effort  and  morale,  which  may  multiply 
or  reduce  the  effectiveness  of  the  economic  factors. 


SHORT-RUN  CAPABILITIES 

Moreover,  in  the  short  run,  aggregate  capabilities  may  be  less  important 
than  superiority  in  actual  mobilized  resources  which  give  the  initial  mili- 
tary advantage  and  therefore  may  be  crucial  in  the  decisions  of  statesmen. 
In  a  war  in  which  both  sides  would  be  prepared  to  make  maximum  use 
of  the  mass  destructive  power  of  nuclear  weapons,  the  initial  advantage 
might  well  prove  final.  On  the  other  hand,  in  such  a  war  the  initial  de- 
struction on  both  sides  might  be  so  great  as  to  nullify  the  importance  of 
industrial  output,  thus  leaving  the  issue  to  land  and  naval  forces  operat- 
ing from  prepared  bases  and  utilizing,  perhaps  decisively,  available  stock 
piles. 

An  interesting  example  of  how  military  success  can  be  built  upon  exist- 
ing capabilities,  without  reference  to  over-all,  long-run  superiority  in 
economic  potential,  is  provided  by  the  effectiveness  of  the  German  stra- 


«5 
V 

u 
u 
3 
o 

V 

M 

ha 

c 


S 

o 


o 


456 


THE  IMPORTANCE  OF  ECONOMIC  FACTORS  457 

tegic  plan  up  to  the  winter  of  1941.  Hitler  relied  on  more  rapid  mobiliza- 
tion of  ground  and  air  striking  units  of  great  initial  power  rather  than  on 
superiority  in  basic  raw  materials  and  industry,  and  he  struck  while  his 
enemies  were  still  preparing.  Emphasis  was  placed  upon  a  tactical  air 
force  as  an  instrument  of  the  blitzkrieg  rather  than  upon  a  strategic  air 
force  to  destroy  war  production  facilities.  This  plan  was  amazingly  suc- 
cessful ( despite  the  setbacks  in  the  air  over  Britain )  until  the  defeats  on 
the  Eastern  Front;  in  September,  1941,  Hitler  was  so  confident  that  he 
directed  large  cutbacks  in  war  production. 

German  plans  for  a  short  war  were  never  successfully  adapted  to  a  long 
war.  Although  arms  production  increased  by  three  times  after  early  1942, 
the  German  economy  was  never  fully  mobilized,  a  fact  which  explains 
its  remarkable  resilience  to  air  attacks.7  Japan's  attack  on  Pearl  Harbor 
was  an  attempt  by  a  power  with  a  relatively  inferior  industrial  base  to 
offset  this  disadvantage  by  surprise  backed  up  by  an  initially  superior 
existing  force. 

The  Western  allies,  on  the  other  hand,  although  tardy  in  their  prepara- 
tions for  war,  were  much  better  equipped  to  fight  a  long  war.  They  pos- 
sessed a  combination  of  a  very  large  resource  base  of  raw  materials, 
labor,  capital,  and  technological  genius  for  converting  these  assets  quickly 
to  war  potential.  Their  problem  was  to  hold  off  the  enemy  until  their 
resources  were  mobilized,  after  which  the  issue  was  never  in  doubt. 

THE  RELATIONSHIP  OF  GEOGRAPHICAL  FACTORS 
TO  ECONOMIC  DEVELOPMENT 

In  their  discussion  of  the  relative  importance  of  location  and  "geograph- 
ical distribution,"  Mackinder  might  well  have  pointed  out  to  Amery  that 
location  is  not  simply  a  matter  of  the  mobility  of  military  forces  in  time  of 
war;  it  also  establishes  and  determines  the  position  of  a  nation  with  re- 
spect to  those  "geographical  conditions"  and  economic  resources  upon 
which  industrial  power  must  be  based.8  It  is  important  also  to  note,  in 
support  of  Mackinder's  thesis,  that  there  are  geographical  features  which, 
unimportant  in  peacetime,  can  critically  affect  the  size  and  composition  of 
the  economic  potential  in  wartime.  One  of  the  most  graphic  illustrations 
of  this  last  point  was  provided  in  both  world  wars  by  Britain's  dependence 
on  sea-borne  imports.  The  curtailment  of  these  by  submarine  warfare  and 

7  For  a  complete  analysis  see  the  United  States  Strategic  Bombing  Survey,  Summary 
Report,  September  30,  1945. 

8  See  Chapter  7. 


458        THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

the  military  and  economic  cost  of  the  convoy  system  placed  a  very  large 
strain  on  the  British  war  economy.9 

Thus,  factors  such  as  location,  size,  shape,  and  other  geographical  rela- 
tionships remain  important  determinants  of  political  and  strategic  policy, 
while  the  related  geographical  pattern  of  economic  development  and  of 
economic  capabilities  is  seen  to  be  equally  pertinent. 

The  extent  of  the  economic  development  of  a  region  is  always  limited 
and  conditioned  by  its  natural  geographical  features.  Some  states  over- 
come the  limitations  of  their  native  environment  by  trade  and  by  colo- 
nization. A  few  areas,  rich  in  natural  resources,  still  remain  "undeveloped." 
But  in  general,  economic  development  has  been  associated  with,  among 
other  things,  some  favorable  combination  of  such  physical  factors  as  cli- 
mate, soil,  topography,  mineral  resources,  and  waterways.  The  influence 
of  these  factors  is  not,  of  course,  confined  to  economic  life,  but  affects  in 
a  unique  and  organic  way  the  growth  and  development  of  a  culture.  How- 
ever, it  is  through  their  influence  on  economic  life  that  they  generally  have 
their  greatest  effect  on  other  aspects  of  human  life.  The  influence  of  a  few 
of  the  more  important  of  these  factors  is  considered  here  very  briefly. 

Climate  and  Economic  Development.  Climate  is  one  of  the  most  im- 
portant geographical  factors  for  economic  development  because  of  its 
effect  on  soils  and  vegetation  and  in  turn  on  human  life  and  activity.10 
Nearly  half  of  the  land  on  the  earth's  surface  is  in  the  intermediate  clima- 
tic regions  of  the  Northern  Hemisphere.  The  economically  developed 
regions  of  the  world  are  concentrated  in  these  regions.  While  there  are 
dense  concentrations  of  population  in  some  of  the  tropical  regions  of 
Asia,  Africa,  and  South  America,  per  capita  agricultural  production  in 
these  areas  is  low  and  industrial  production  negligible.  The  explana- 
tion for  the  difference  is  to  be  found  partly  in  the  climate,  through  the 
effect  of  temperature  and  rainfall  on  soil  and  vegetation,  and  partly 
in  historical  and  cultural  factors.  In  tropical  regions  high  tempera- 
ture and  high  humidity  have  an  enervating  effect  on  both  physical  and 
mental  activity.  Rainfall,  or  the  lack  of  it,  and  its  seasonal  distribution 
will  affect  the  fertility  of  the  soil  and  the  growth  of  crops.  In  the  tropical 

9  See  A.  P.  Usher,  "The  Steam  and  Steel  Complex  and  International  Relations,"  in 
Technology  and  International  Relations,  Wm.  F.  Ogborn,  ed.    (Chicago,   1949). 

10  For  a  good  brief  discussion  of  the  effects  of  climate  on  human  activity  see  J.  H. 
Stembridge,  The  World:  A  General  Regional  Geography,  1953,  Ch.  7.  For  influence 
of  climate  on  economic  activity  see  L.  D.  Stamp  and  S.  C.  Gilmour,  Chisholm's 
Handbook  of  Commercial  Geography,  14th  ed.  (New  York,  1954),  pp.  22-52.  These 
however,  are  fairly  elementary.  P.  Gourou's  The  Tropical  World  (Engl,  translation, 
London,  1953),  is  a  much  more  sophisticated  examination  of  certain  aspects  of  the 
problem. 


THE  IMPORTANCE  OF  ECONOMIC  FACTORS  459 

rain  forests  there  is  so  much  precipitation  that  leaching  of  the  soil  tends 
to  deprive  it  of  fertility.  The  hot  desert  regions  like  the  Sahara  or  the 
great  Australian  desert  are  practically  uncultivable  and  uninhabitable. 

The  geographical  conditions  which  in  the  past  were  favorable  to  the 
growth  of  civilizations  appear  to  have  been  different  from  those  which 
exist  today  in  association  with  a  high  degree  of  economic  development. 
Marston  Bates  J1  has  pointed  out  that  all  three  pre-Columbian  civi- 
lizations in  the  Americas,  the  Incas,  the  Mayas,  and  the  Aztecs,  were 
tropical  in  origin  and  did  not  spread  far  beyond  the  tropics.  Bates  cites 
the  two  extinct  cultures  of  Ceylon  and  Cambodia  to  demonstrate  that  a 
very  high  level  of  social  life  and  development  can  be  attained  in  tropical 
regions.  That  of  Ceylon  depended  on  a  remarkable  system  of  reservoirs 
for  storing  water  from  the  seasonal  rains.  It  collapsed  when  the  dykes  fell 
into  disrepair  in  the  course  of  internecine  wars  in  the  thirteenth  and  four- 
teenth centuries.  The  Khmer  Empire  in  Cambodia  endured  for  five  hun- 
dred years  and  produced  a  magnificent  art  and  architecture  before  col- 
lapsing in  the  tenth  century  from  unknown  causes. 

Today  the  regions  of  the  tropics  are  among  the  most  underdeveloped 
of  the  world.  This  is  especially  true  of  the  equatorial  rain  forests,  as  in 
the  Amazon  and  Congo  river  valleys.  Rain  falls  throughout  the  year,  tem- 
peratures are  uniformly  high,  and  the  landscape  is  covered  with  a  dense 
tropical  forest.  Some  of  the  wood  is  valuable,  like  mahogany  and  ebony, 
but  is  difficult  to  reach  and  costly  to  harvest.  Malaya,  the  Philippines,  and 
Indonesia  are  in  this  belt  but  their  forests  are  less  dense  because  of  their 
proximity  to  the  sea  and  here  conditions  are  more  favorable  to  agriculture 
and  the  growth  of  population. 

Other  parts  of  the  Tropical  Zones  are  more  favorable  to  man.  These  are 
the  tropical  grass  lands  and  savannas  and  especially  the  monsoon  lands. 
The  former  are  found  on  both  sides  of  the  equatorial  forests,  in  South 
America  (Orinoco  Basin  and  Brazilian  highlands)  in  Africa  (Sudan),  in 
the  drier  parts  of  India,  in  the  Philippines,  and  in  the  north  and  east  of 
Australia.  The  temperature  is  uniformly  high,  rain  falls  during  the  summer 
months  and  the  winter  season  is  dry.  These  regions  are  primarily  agricul- 
tural. 

The  monsoon  lands  are  economically,  as  well  as  in  many  other  ways, 
the  most  important  of  the  tropical  regions.  With  their  wet,  hot  summers 
and  dry  winter  seasons  they  are  extraordinarily  well-suited  to  certain  types 
of  agriculture  (especially  rice)  and  have  thus  become  one  of  the  most 
densely  populated  regions  of  the  earth.  The  monsoon  climate,  which  is 

11  Where  Winter  Never  Comes  (New  York,  1953). 


460        THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

well  marked  in  India,  Southeast  Asia,  Southern  China,  and  Northern  Aus- 
tralia is  characterized  by  heavy  rains  during  summer,  as  winds  blow  from 
sea  to  land,  and  a  dry  season  in  winter  when  the  winds  blow  in  the 
opposite  direction.  In  northern  hemisphere  monsoon  lands,  like  India  and 
Burma,  the  cool  dry  season  lasts  from  November  to  February,  the  hot 
season  from  March  to  June,  and  the  rainy  season  from  June  to  October. 
In  the  wetter  regions  where  the  annual  rainfall  may  be  eighty  inches  or 
more,  the  forests  resemble  those  of  the  equatorial  belt  and  the  crops  in- 
clude rice,  tea,  and  jute.  If  the  rainy  season  lasts  as  long  as  six  to  seven 
months,  as  in  Pakistan,  cotton  and  sugar  cane  can  be  grown. 

Central  China  and  Japan  also  receive  monsoon  rains  and  are  some- 
times referred  to  as  subtropical  monsoon  regions.  They  are  also  among 
the  most  densely  populated  regions  of  the  world. 

Our  own  Western  civilization  flourished  first  in  the  Mediterranean,  but 
its  greatest  development  has  occurred  in  the  cooler  intermediate  regions 
where  man  has  met  the  challenge  of  the  seasons.  Next  to  the  monsoon 
lands  of  Asia,  the  industrial  areas  of  Europe  and  the  United  States  are  the 
most  populous  areas  of  the  world.  Most  of  the  land  and  large  industrial 
areas  of  North  America  and  Europe  are  in  a  cool  temperate  climate. 

New  England  and  the  North  Atlantic  states  are  mostly  in  an  eastern 
maritime  type  of  climate,  as  in  Manchuria,  part  of  North  China,  Korea, 
Hokaido,  and  Sakhalin.  Most  of  Western  Europe  and  the  United  Kingdom 
are  in  a  cooler  and  more  humid  West  coast  marine  climate.  These  are 
usually  comparatively  highly  industrialized  regions.  The  former  regions 
have  a  more  extreme  climate  than  the  latter  and  are  hot  in  summer  and 
cold  in  winter,  have  a  light  to  moderate  rainfall,  with  the  prevailing 
winds  off-shore.  The  West  coast  marine-type  regions  are  subjected  to 
onshore  westerly  winds  and  thus  have  an  insular  climate  marked  by  cool 
summers  and  mild  winters  with  rainfall  fairly  well  distributed  through- 
out the  year. 

Russia's  continental  climate  has  been  comparatively  unfavorable  to 
economic  development,  with  hot  summers  and  winter  temperatures  below 
the  freezing  point  except  in  the  Crimea.  Over  most  of  the  country  the 
annual  rainfall  is  not  more  than  twenty  inches.  Most  of  the  coast  line  lies 
so  far  north  as  to  be  icebound  for  as  long  as  six  months  in  the  year.  Inland 
waterways  are  similarly  affected;  while  the  completion  of  the  Don-Volga 
Canal  makes  possible  water  transportation  between  the  Baltic  and  White 
seas  in  the  north  to  the  Caspian  and  Black  seas  in  the  south,  even  the 
southern  portions  of  these  routes  are  frozen  for  three  months. 

From  the  brief  discussion  given  above,  it  will  be  seen  that  both  the 


THE  IMPORTANCE  OF  ECONOMIC  FACTORS  461 

tropical  and  the  intermediate  regions  have  been  found  conducive  to  civili- 
zation. In  both  zones  are  regions  which  are  unfavorable  to  life  and  to  eco- 
nomic activity,  the  equatorial  rain  forests  and  hot  deserts  in  the  tropics 
and  the  deserts  of  Iran,  and  Gobi.  The  temperate  deserts  are  more  easily 
reclaimable  through  irrigation  than  the  tropical  deserts,  and  the  tropical 
rain  forests,  of  the  Amazon  at  any  rate,  still  more  or  less  successfully  resist 
human  encroachment.  In  both  the  tropics  and  the  intermediate  zones  there 
are  areas  of  great  population  concentration— the  tropical  monsoon  lands 
of  Asia  which  have  been  almost  exclusively  agricultural  or  extractive  in 
their  development,  and  the  industrialized  regions  of  Europe  and  North 
America.  Experience  thus  suggests  that  intermediate  climates  furnish  the 
most  favorable  conditions  for  diversified  economic  development,  includ- 
ing industrialization. 

All  the  highly  developed  countries  lie  in  latitudes  35°  N  to  70°  N.  This 
is  Huntington's  "very  high  energy"  region.12  He  ascribes  the  high  eco- 
nomic development  of  most  of  the  countries  in  this  zone  to  the  invigorat- 
ing effects  on  man  of  the  favorable  climate.  Huntington  eliminates  relief, 
soil,  minerals,  power  resources,  and  waterways  as  major  factors  shaping 
the  pattern  of  world  economic  development.  While  a  favorable  climate 
undoubtedly  has  contributed  to  the  economic  progress  of  the  developed 
countries,  the  importance  attached  to  it  by  Huntington  appears  to  be 
exaggerated.  On  the  contrary,  it  is  becoming  increasingly  apparent  that 
the  densely  populated  countries  of  the  monsoon  areas  of  India  and  China 
are  underdeveloped  precisely  because  the  climate  and  other  physical 
factors  were  so  favorable  to  human  life  and  population  growth  in  the  pre- 
industrial  rice  economies,  while  industrialization  was  possible  in  North- 
western Europe  at  least  partly  because  the  population  was  still  relatively 
small  in  relation  to  land  and  other  resources  when  the  new  era  began.13 

Soils  and  Vegetation.14  Soils  and  vegetation  are  of  basic  importance  to 
agriculture  and  forestry.  If  the  soil  of  a  region  lacks  the  ability  to  produce 
agricultural  and  forest  products  it  is  likely  that  the  region  will  be  unin- 
habitable. Moreover  the  fertility  of  the  soil  is  important  to  the  industrial 
stages  of  economic  development;  usually  a  community  must  be  able  to 

12  E.  Huntington,  Civilization  and  Climate,  3rd  ed.  (New  York,  1939). 

13  See  especially  Gourou,  op.  cit.,  pp.  1-5  and  99-112;  also  S.  Kuznet,  Under- 
developed Countries  and  the  Fre-industrial  Phase  in  the  Advanced  Countries,  an 
unpublished  paper  delivered  at  the  World  Population  Conference,  Rome,  September, 
1954.  See  also  A.  P.  Usher,  "Population  and  Settlement  in  Eurasia,"  Geographic 
Review,  Vol.  10  ( 1930),  pp.  110-132. 

14  This  discussion  is  based  to  a  large  extent  on  Stamp  and  Gilmour,  op.  cit.,  pp. 
53-64);  cf.  also  M.  S.  Anderson,  Geography  of  Living  Tilings  (New  York,  1954), 
pp.  121-168. 


462 


THE  IMPORTANCE  OF  ECONOMIC  FACTORS  463 

produce  a  surplus  of  foodstuffs  in  order  to  release  part  of  its  population 
to  other  employment  before  it  can  develop  the  facilities  for  manufactur- 
ing, transportation,  and  trade.  This  is  an  important  part  of  the  problem  of 
economic  development,  for  example,  in  a  country  like  India,  which  has 
difficulty  in  producing  enough  foodstuff  for  its  vast  population.  The  low 
level  of  per  capita  food  production  is  in  turn  partly  a  consequence  of  in- 
ability of  the  farmers  to  afford  fertilization,  and  partly  a  function  of  mere 
numbers  of  the  population,  for  the  soil  and  climate  throughout  most  of 
India  is  favorable  to  cultivation. 

Soils  and  vegetation  are  reflections  of  climate.  The  soil  of  many  arid 
lands  is  often  very  rich  in  minerals  and  only  the  lack  of  rainfall  prevents 
the  growth  of  grasses  or  crops.  The  great  climatic  regions  of  the  world 
have  their  own  distinctive  soil  properties,  since  the  soil  is  due  to  the 
weathering  of  rock  under  different  atmospheric  conditions,  and  is  subject 
to  different  effects  of  vegetable  and  animal  life.  However  many  soils  are 
aclimatic,  having  within  the  same  climatic  region,  numerous  local  varia- 
tions depending  on  the  characteristics  of  the  parent  material.  Consequently 
the  crop  yield  of  one  region  may  be  much  greater  or  less  than  that  of 
another  with  the  same  climate. 

The  productivity  of  land  for  agricultural  purposes  depends  on  the  fer- 
tility of  the  soil,  and  on  the  degree  and  seasonal  variation  of  rainfall  and 
temperature.  About  two-thirds  of  the  earth's  land  surface  is  unsuited  for 
agriculture  because  of  insufficient  precipitation  and  low  temperature,  and 
a  large  part  of  the  balance  is  unusable  because  of  topography  ( Fig.  14-2 ) . 
About  one-fifth  of  the  land  area  has  temperature,  rainfall,  and  topography 
in  the  right  combinations,  but  less  than  10  per  cent  is  fully  suited  for 
agricultural  production,  the  proportion  ranging  from  less  than  3  per  cent 
in  Oceania  to  37  per  cent  in  Europe.15 

Agricultural  production  does  not  vary  uniformly  with  natural  fertility 
and  climate,  because  of  differences  in  the  skills  of  farm  populations  and 
the  amounts  of  capital  employed.  The  most  productive  agricultural  re- 
gions are  Northwestern  Europe,  the  North  Central  and  Middle  Atlantic 
United  States,  the  valleys  of  the  Indus  and  Ganges  in  India  and  Pakistan, 
and  Southeastern  China.  Smaller  areas  of  high  production  are  found  in 
coastal  Argentina  and  Brazil,  the  southern  Ukraine,  the  lower  Nile  valley 
and  southern  Australia.  Asia  and  Africa,  although  they  contain  more  than 
60  per  cent  of  the  world's  population,  account  for  just  over  30  per  cent 
of  world  agricultural  output.  Output  per  capita  is  low  in  Africa  because 

15  W.  S.  and  E.  S.  Woytinsky,  World  Population  and  Production  (New  York,  1954), 
p.  316,  Table  154. 


464       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

of  primitive  techniques,  in  Asia  because  of  scarcity  of  land.  Europe  (in- 
cluding the  U.S.S.R.),  the  Americas,  and  Oceania,  with  a  much  smaller 
population,  produce  70  per  cent  of  the  world's  agricultural  output  by 
value. 

Agricultural  production  is  coming  more  and  more  to  depend  on  con- 
trolled plant  food  ( fertilizers )  and  controlled  water  ( irrigation ) .  Farmers 
were  once  able  to  rely  on  the  organic  processes  of  animal  manures  and 
leguminous  plants  to  restore  the  fertility  of  the  soil  but  the  intensive  agri- 
culture of  today  requires  vast  quantities  of  "commercial"  fertilizers.  World 
consumption  of  the  three  main  commercial  fertilizers,  nitrogen,  phosphate, 
and  potash,  in  1950  to  1951  was  almost  13.5  million  tons.  Even  with  the 
use  of  such  fertilizers  the  soil  gradually  becomes  depleted.  The  destruc- 
tion of  agricultural  soil  by  wind  and  water  erosion  after  the  natural  cover 
has  been  removed  is  even  more  serious,  and  much  good  crop  land,  even 
in  the  United  States,  has  been  totally  destroyed  in  this  way.  Topsoil  that 
has  taken  thousands  of  years  to  build,  has  been  washed  away  completely 
in  two  generations.  Large  areas  of  former  coffee  land  in  Brazil  have  been 
thus  depleted.  Erosion  over  the  centuries  in  China,  India,  and  the  Middle 
East  has  destroyed  millions  of  acres,  and  in  the  latter  region,  "The  ruins 
of  ancient  water  works  explain  eloquently  why  the  land  ...  is  dry  and 
sterile."  16 

Irrigation  has  long  been  employed  as  a  remedy  for  the  deficiency  of 
rainfall,  especially  with  rivers  like  the  Nile  and  the  Euphrates  which  regu- 
larly overflow  their  banks.  Such  irrigation  by  inundation  provided  not 
only  water  but  fertilizing  sediment  which,  if  the  floods  destroyed  one 
crop,  guaranteed  the  success  of  the  next.  However,  since  water  is  needed 
most  during  the  dry  seasons,  the  old  inundation  canals  have  generally 
been  replaced  by  dams  and  perennial  canals.  In  the  United  States  we  are 
accustomed  to  irrigation  works  being  employed  to  reclaim  the  western 
desert  lands  and  forget  that  irrigation  systems  are  an  absolutely  indispen- 
sable part  of  the  agricultural  economies  of  a  number  of  ancient  lands. 
Most  varieties  of  rice,  upon  which  so  large  a  part  of  the  world's  population 
depends  as  a  staple  food,  must  be  grown  in  irrigated  fields  and  flooded 
at  a  certain  stage  of  growth;  if  this  cannot  be  accomplished  by  the  rains 
or  inundation,  the  water  must  be  stored  and  released  at  the  proper  times. 
Occasionally,  in  some  districts  of  India  (never  in  all),  the  monsoon  rains 
fail  and  famine  occurs  where  irrigation  is  not  practiced.  In  other  areas, 
such  as  the  Coromandel  Coast  of  India,  the  annual  rainfall  is  concentrated 
in  a  short  period  of  a  few  weeks  and  must  be  stored  in  tanks.  However, 

16  Ibid.,  p.  479. 


THE  IMPORTANCE  OF  ECONOMIC  FACTORS  465 

in  the  deltas  of  this  coast,  three  crops  of  rice  a  year  are  produced  in  land 
irrigated  by  canals. 

The  necessity  of  irrigating  rice  ( as  well  as  the  scarcity  of  arable  land ) 
has  in  some  countries  such  as  the  Philippines,  China,  and  Yemen  produced 
remarkable  instances  of  terrace  cultivation.  In  our  own  time,  the  counter- 
part of  these  marvelous  human  modifications  seems  to  be  the  planned 
development  of  entire  river  valleys  to  provide  not  only  for  irrigation  but 
also  for  flood  control,  navigation,  and  hydro-electric  power  production. 
The  most  remarkable  example  of  modern  river  valley  development  is  the 
Tennessee  Valley  a  7  in  which,  up  to  July  1,  1949,  some  $800  million  had 
been  expended  for  these  purposes.  Such  measures,  together  with  the 
measures  to  enlarge  the  supply  or  productivity  of  arable  land  by  soil  and 
forest  conservation  and  by  reclamation,  take  considerable  time  and  re- 
quire large  investment  outlays  which  are  often  beyond  the  means  of 
overpopulated,  underdeveloped  countries. 

Mineral  Resources  and  Energy.  In  the  period  between  World  Wars  I 
and  II  it  was  fashionable  to  interpret  political  rivalries  in  terms  of  the 
struggle  for  raw  materials,  especially  minerals.  Imperial  powers  were 
depicted  as  grasping  for  colonies  to  provide  supplies  of  raw  materials  and 
markets  for  finished  products.  The  rise  of  Nazism  in  Germany  was  ex- 
plained in  part  as  an  aspect  of  the  German  drive  to  recover  colonial 
sources  of  raw  materials  and  to  acquire  "lebensraum."  In  Japan,  perhaps 
more  than  in  Germany,  the  need  to  expand  the  economy,  even  for  peace- 
ful purposes,  was  a  real  one.  Home  supplies  of  iron  ore  and  coking  coal 
were  limited  and  petroleum  was  produced  ( in  insufficient  quantities )  only 
in  Japanese  Sakhalin.  It  was  against  this  background  that  Prime  Minister 
Churchill  and  President  Roosevelt  included  in  the  Atlantic  Charter  a 
phrase  supporting  the  "principle"  of  equal  access  to  raw  materials. 

The  present  geographical  pattern  of  industrial  development  is  still 
based  largely  on  two  minerals,  coal  and  iron  ore.  In  addition  to  its  impor- 
tance as  a  source  of  energy,  coal  is  an  essential  raw  material  in  the  steel 
and  chemical  industries.  Accordingly,  one  common  and  important  geo- 
graphical characteristic  of  almost  all  highly  developed  countries  is 
the  presence  of  fairly  plentiful  supplies  of  coal  and  iron  ore,  either 
within  their  own  national  boundaries  or  close  at  hand.  Thus,  while  Ger- 
many is  deficient  in  iron  ore,  it  draws  on  the  rich  supplies  of  Lorraine  for 
its  steel-making  industries.  France,  short  of  coal,  in  turn  obtains  supplies 
from  the  nearby  Ruhr  (cf.  Fig.  17-1).  Lack  of  coal  undoubtedly  was  a 
factor  retarding  the  development  of  Mediterranean  Europe. 

17  See  p.  579. 


466       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

Today  no  nation  has  adequate  domestic  supplies  of  all  minerals  and 
very  few  even  approach  self-sufficiency.  Even  the  United  States,  generally 
regarded  as  the  nation  most  liberally  endowed  with  natural  resources,  is 
deficient  in  a  number  of  minerals  including  some  that  are  essential  in  time 
of  war,  such  as  tin,  nickel,  and  manganese.  These  deficiencies  must  be 
viewed  in  the  light  of  our  ability  to  stockpile  large  quantities  of  some  and 
to  devise  adequate  substitutes  for  others.18  Similarly  the  U.S.S.R.  and 
satellites,  although  deliberately  striving  for  autarky  (an  economic  poten- 
tial for  war  not  dependent  on  foreign  supplies),  import  large  quantities 
of  many  minerals  including  copper,  lead,  zinc,  nickel,  quartz  crystals,  and 
industrial  diamonds.  The  real  object  of  concern  in  both  countries  probably 
is  not  with  its  materials  position  in  the  event  of  a  war  in  the  relatively  near 
future,  but  rather  with  its  long-run  ability  to  continue  to  supply  increasing 
quantities  of  the  exhaustible  mineral  raw  materials  to  a  rapidly  growing 
industrial  machine.  In  the  future,  the  search  by  developed  countries  for 
mineral  and  other  raw  materials  to  supplement  domestic  supplies,  rather 
than  the  search  for  markets  or  profits,  is  likely  to  be  the  principal  incentive 
for  the  exploitation  of  undeveloped  areas. 

Much  more  basic  to  economic  and  industrial  power  than  the  minerals 
per  se,  are  the  sources  of  mechanical  energy,  coal,  petroleum,  natural  gas, 
and  hydro-power.  Of  these  coal  is  the  most  widely  used  and  in  the  actual 
historical  development  of  industrialism  the  most  important.  It  has  been 
aptly  said  that  no  geographical  factor  is  more  significant  in  relation  to  the 
economic  history  of  the  past  two  hundred  years  than  the  fact  that  when 
Western  man  was  ready  to  apply  the  steam  engine  to  industrial  power, 
and  to  make  steel  with  coke  instead  of  charcoal,  he  found  enormous  quan- 
tities of  steam  and  coking  coal  literally  under  his  feet,  in  the  British  Isles, 
in  the  Appalachian  basin,  in  western  and  central  Europe.  While  oil  and 
hydraulic  power  have  become  of  increasing  importance  as  sources  of 
energy  in  the  twentieth  century,  coal  is  still  the  chief  supplier  of  fuel  and 
power.  In  1949  nearly  half  of  the  world's  energy  was  supplied  by  coal  and 
lignite.19  Petroleum,  next  in  economic  importance  (though  of  prime  mili- 
tary importance ) ,  accounted  for  only  about  20  per  cent  of  the  world  total. 
Petroleum  and  its  products  are,  of  course,  easier  to  handle  and  cheaper 
to  transport  than  coal.  In  the  United  States  petroleum  is  threatening  the 
primacy  of  coal  as  a  source  of  energy  due  to  the  remarkable  development 
of  motor  transportation.  In  Europe,  which  produces  little  natural  oil,  coal 

18  Cf.  E.   S.   Mason,  "American  Security  and  Access  to  Raw   Materials,"  World 
Politics,  Vol.  1,  No.  2,  pp.  147-160. 

19  United  Nations,  World  Energy  in  Selected  Years,  1929-1950  (New  York,  1952). 


THE  IMPORTANCE  OF  ECONOMIC  FACTORS  467 

accounted  for  over  80  per  cent  of  all  energy  produced,  and  in  the  U.S.S.R. 
over  60  per  cent.2"  However,  European  countries  are  building  refineries 
and  shifting  increasingly  to  petroleum  as  coal  becomes  more  costly. 

The  geographic  distribution  of  the  producing  petroleum  reserves  is 
quite  different  from  that  of  coal,  the  three  principal  areas  being  ( 1 )  the 
Gulf  Coast,  Mid-continent  (U.S.)  and  Caribbean  (Venezuela),  (2)  the 
Near  East  (Black  Sea,  Persian  Gulf)  and  (3)  Far  East  (Indonesia).  Thus 
a  large  share  of  today's  petroleum  production  comes  from  relatively 
"underdeveloped"  areas,  from  areas  discovered  and  developed  by  Ameri- 
can, British,  or  Dutch  companies  without  whose  capital  and  technical 
direction  it  could  not  have  been  produced.  The  geographical  distribution 
of  water  power  likewise  does  not  support  theories  of  physical  determinism 
in  explaining  economic  development,  since  water-power  potential  occurs 
in  heavy  concentration  in  many  underdeveloped  areas,  in  South  America, 
Asia,  and  Africa.  The  highly  developed  countries  ( Fig.  14-3 ) ,  the  United 
States,  Germany,  Sweden,  Switzerland,  Japan  ( the  United  Kingdom  has  a 
very  small  water-potential),  have  all  utilized  their  hydro-electric  poten- 
tial up  to  40  per  cent  or  50  per  cent  or  more.  The  availability  of  water 
power  in  under-developed  areas  poor  in  coal  and  petroleum  (Brazil) 
should  facilitate  the  industrial  development  of  those  areas. 

NONGEOGRAPHICAL  FACTORS 

Geographical  factors  thus  have  generally  a  significant  effect  on  the 
economic  development  of  a  region.  Except  in  a  few  isolated  instances 
however  it  is  in  concrete  situations  almost  impossible  to  separate  out  and 
assess  the  importance  of  geographical  relative  to  nongeographical  factors. 
It  is  fairly  obvious  that  areas  like  the  Sahara  Desert  or  the  Canadian 
Arctic  have  been  of  little  economic  consequence  to  date,  and  may  well 
never  amount  to  much  because  of  this  inhospitable  climate  and  paucity 
of  resources.  The  United  Kingdom  could  not  have  developed  a  large  steel 
industry  without  coal  and  iron  ore.  The  matchless  resources  of  the  United 
States  have  been  a  major  factor  in  its  unparalleled  economic  growth.  For 
most  areas,  however,  including  the  United  States,  the  relationship  be- 
tween the  degree  of  economic  development  and  the  geographic  environ- 
ment is  much  less  direct  than  in  our  Sahara  desert  and  Arctic  Canada 
examples.  Nongeographical  factors  have  commonly  been  no  less  signifi- 
cant and  frequently  more  important  than  the  physical  environment  in 

20  The  reasons  for  the  U.S.S.R.'s  heavy  dependence  on  coal  are  given  below,  on 
p.  475  ff. 


468 


THE  IMPORTANCE  OF  ECONOMIC  FACTORS  469 

shaping  a  country's  economic  development.  How  else  can  we  explain  why 
countries  like  Switzerland  and  Denmark  have  reached  much  higher  levels 
of  economic  development  than  Spain  or  Italy,  though  less  well-endowed 
with  basic  resources?  Or  what  accounted  for  the  economic  ascendency  of 
the  United  Kingdom  over  France  and  Germany  from  the  middle  of  the 
sixteenth  century  until  almost  the  close  of  the  nineteenth,  despite  inferior 
natural  resources?  Why  was  the  economic  development  of  the  U.S.S.R., 
which  is  second  only  to  the  United  States  in  natural  resources,  delayed 
until  almost  the  beginning  of  the  twentieth  century?  How  and  why  did 
Japan  progress  so  rapidly  on  so  limited  a  resource  base  in  so  short  a 
period?  To  answer  these  questions  we  must  consider  chiefly  nongeo- 
graphical  factors. 

The  economic  development  process  depends  not  only  on  the  geographi- 
cal environment  but  also  on  the  attitude  of  the  people  toward  economic 
progress  and  on  prevailing  social,  political,  economic,  and  legal  institu- 
tions.21 The  present  pattern  of  world  economic  development  is  largely  the 
outgrowth  of  historical  changes  in  Europe  which  must  be  traced  back  to 
the  Middle  Ages,  and  which  culminated  in  the  so-called  Industrial  Revo- 
lution in  the  eighteenth  and  nineteenth  centuries.  This  was  not  a  revolu- 
tion in  the  sense  of  a  sudden  and  radical  movement  of  population  out  of 
agriculture  into  industry  and  a  change  from  handicraft  to  machine  meth- 
ods of  production.  Rather,  the  industrial  revolution  was  a  speeding  up  of 
a  gradual  process  of  innovation  and  modernization  in  agriculture,  com- 
merce, and  industry  which  had  been  under  way  in  Western  Europe  and 
particularly  in  Great  Britain  since  the  fifteenth  century.  Two  eighteenth 
century  technical  inventions  played  a  major  role  in  the  Industrial  Revolu- 
tion. They  were  ( 1 )  the  invention  of  the  steam  engine  and  its  application 
to  industry,  transportation,  and  agriculture,  and  (2)  the  "puddling  proc- 
ess" which  made  possible  the  widespread  use  of  coal  in  the  manufacture 
of  bar  iron.  This  change  in  the  tempo  of  economic  development  has  been 
described  by  G.  N.  Trevelyan  in  his  History  of  England  as  follows:  "Up 
to  the  Industrial  Revolution,  economic  and  social  change,  though  con- 
tinuous, has  the  pace  of  a  slowly  moving  stream,  but  in  the  days  of  Watt 
and  Stephenson  it  has  acquired  the  momentum  of  water  over  a  mill-dam, 
distracting  to  the  eye  of  the  spectator."  22 

The  Industrial  Revolution  began  first  in  Great  Britain.  "It  was  the  enter- 
prise and  industry  of  eighteenth-century  Britain  that  first  realized  the 

21  For  a  brief  summary  of  the  psychological  and  social  pre-requisites  of  economic 
progress  see  the  United  Nations  study,  Measures  For  the  Economic  Development  oj 
Under-Developed  Countries  (New  York,  1951),  pp.  13-16. 

22  History  of  England,  Vol.  3  (New  York,  1954),  o.  132. 


470       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

dream  of  the  Renaissance  scientists  and  brought  the  forces  of  nature  under 
human  control  by  scientific  means."  The  forces  of  nature  were  abundantly 
present  in  the  form  of  coal  and  iron  ore,  but  their  subjection  by  the  new 
scientific  knowledge  might  have  waited  in  vain  "as  was  the  case  with 
Greek  mechanics  in  the  ancient  world  had  it  not  been  for  the  social  ini- 
tiative of  British  industry,"  an  initiative  which  derived  in  turn  from  the 
moral  and  social  ideals  of  Puritanism.23  The  history  of  this  expansion 
illustrates  the  extent  to  which  economic— indeed,  all  human— progress  has 
depended  on  an  intricate  relationship  of  material,  geographical,  and  cul- 
tural factors  rather  than  on  any  one  single  set  of  causes.  The  actual 
balance  of  political  power  at  any  given  time  is  indeed  the  product  of  all 
these  different  factors. 

23  C.  Dawson,  Progress  and  Religion  (New  York,  1938),  pp.  213-215. 


CHAPTER 


15 


The  Growing  Economic 
Strength  or  the  Sino-Soviet  Bloc 


A.    The  Soviet  Union 

We  will  begin  our  consideration  of  the  present  world  pattern  of  eco- 
nomic capabilities  with  the  Union  of  Soviet  Socialist  Republics  (U.S.S.R. ) 
and  its  system  of  satellite  states  usually  referred  to  as  the  Soviet  bloc.  It  is 
the  great  increase  in  the  economic,  political,  and  military  power  of  this 
group  of  states  in  the  past  three  decades  that,  more  than  any  other  factor, 
accounts  for  the  present  tension  in  international  political  relationships. 
The  name  often  given  to  this  tension— the  East- West  struggle— suggests 
cultural  rather  than  geographical  issues.  At  the  same  time,  the  locus  of 
Communist  strength  is  truly  in  the  Soviet  East  and  China,  while  the  pole 
around  which  the  anti-Communist  states  cluster  is  the  economic  colossus 
of  the  West,  the  United  States.  This  relationship  is  an  especially  fruitful 
field  of  study  for  the  student  of  political  geography  because  it  permits  him 
to  compare  the  influence  of  geographical  factors  in  two  rapidly  growing 
economic  systems  with  widely  differing  social  and  political  institutions. 
In  the  one,  the  United  States,  it  is  customary  to  ascribe  the  extraordinary 
progress  of  technology  and  industry  to  a  favorable  combination  of  abun- 
dant resources  and  free  enterprise.  In  the  other,  the  U.S.S.R.,  while  natural 
resources  are  abundant,  they  were  clearly  only  a  necessary,  and  not  a 
sufficient,  condition  of  economic  progress.  Until  the  Revolution  of  1917 
Russia  was  industrially  one  of  the  most  backward  European  states,  while 
thereafter  the  country  underwent  the  most  rapid  and  far-reaching  eco- 

471 


472       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

nomic  development  in  modern  history  under  the  force  of  a  new  economic 
philosophy. 

One  way  of  showing  how  the  economic  capabilities  of  the  U.S.S.R.  have 
increased  under  the  Communist  regime  relative  to  those  of  Western  coun- 
tries is  to  compare  production  of  important  commodities  and  services.  For 
example,  in  1930  steel  production  in  Russia  was  only  one-seventh  of  that 
in  the  United  States  and  less  than  one-fourth  of  the  combined  output  of 
France,  Germany,  and  Belgium.1  In  1955  steel  production  in  the  U.S.S.R. 
was  over  two-fifths  of  United  States  output  and  actually  exceeded  the 
combined  output  of  the  three  Western  European  countries.2  If  steel  pro- 
duction in  the  United  Kingdom  is  added  to  the  three  countries  above, 
Russian  steel  output  increased  from  a  ratio  of  less  than  20  per  cent  to  over 
70  per  cent. 

If  the  comparison  is  made  with  coal  we  find  the  U.S.S.R.  increasing 
from  about  10  per  cent  of  the  United  States  output  and  8  per  cent  of  the 
four  Western  European  countries  in  1930  to  about  74  per  cent  and  about 
68  per  cent  respectively  in  1955.3  These  increases  suggest  an  extraordinary 
expansion  in  the  Russian  economy  relative  to  rates  of  growth  in  the  United 
States  and  Western  Europe.  The  result  is  that  by  1955  the  U.S.S.R.,  with 
a  population  of  217  million,  had  a  gross  national  product  estimated  at 
$149  billion  or  $687  per  capita  compared  with  $300  billion,  or  $891  per 
capita  for  the  free  countries  of  Western  Europe  with  a  population  of 
337  million. 

GENERAL  FACTORS 

After  the  revolution  of  1917,  in  which  Finland  and  the  Baltic  states 
secured  their  independence,  the  new  U.S.S.R.  extended  over  an  area  of 
eight  and  a  quarter  million  square  miles,  with  a  population  of  perhaps 
170  million.  The  border  adjustments  after  World  War  II  and  the  re- 
absorption  of  the  Baltic  States  increased  the  area  to  8,708,000  square 
miles,  as  compared  with  3,556,000  square  miles  in  the  United  States.4  This 
vast  area  extends  over  170  degrees  of  longitude  and  more  than  45  degrees 
of  latitude,  but  it  lies  entirely  in  the  Temperate  and  Arctic  Zones.  There 

1W.  S.  and  E.  S.  Woytinsky,  World  Population  and  Production  (New  York,  1954), 
Table  466,  p.  1118. 

2  Department  of  State,  Indicators  of  Economic  Strength  of  Western  Europe, 
Canada,  the  United  States,  and  the  Soviet  Bloc,  1955,  IR  7247,  May  9,  1956. 

3  Comparisons  for  1930  based  on  Woytinsky,  op.  cit.,  Table  366,  p.  870.  For  1953, 
from  Department  of  State,  IR  7247,  including  West  Germany  only. 

4  L.  D.  Stamp  and  S.  C.  Gilmour,  Chisholms  Handbook  of  Commercial  Geography, 
14th  ed.  (New  York,  1954),  pp.  493  ff. 


GROWING  ECONOMIC  STRENGTH  OF  SINO-SOVIET  BLOC    473 

are  a  number  of  characteristics  of  this  land  mass  which  are  significant  to 
its  economic  development.5 

European  Russia,  though  an  enormous  country,  is  almost  entirely  flat. 
Western  Siberia,  separated  from  Russia  in  Europe  by  the  modest  heights 
of  the  Urals,  is  a  continuation  of  the  Great  European  Plain,  while  Eastern 
Siberia,  east  of  the  River  Lena,  is  a  low  plateau.  Only  the  Soviet  Far  East 
is  mountainous  and  inaccessible.  Distances  between  cities  are  great,  and 
road  and  rail  construction  is  rendered  difficult  by  the  softness  of  the 
ground  and  the  lack  of  stone  and  timber  through  large  areas  of  the  south. 
The  rivers,  such  as  the  Volga  which  flows  into  the  Caspian  Sea,  and  the 
Dnieper  and  the  Don  which  flow  into  the  Black  Sea,  are  adaptable  to 
navigation,  but  most  of  the  U.S.S.R.  is  far  from  the  sea  and  has  a  conti- 
nental climate  with  extremes  of  hot  and  cold.  Consequently  the  water- 
ways are  frozen  during  the  winter,  and  in  Siberia,  where  they  flow  north- 
ward to  the  Arctic  Ocean,  they  are  usable  only  a  few  months  in  the  year. 
It  has  often  been  remarked  that  the  rivers  of  the  U.S.S.R.  run  in  the 
wrong  directions  (north  and  south  instead  of  east  and  west),  and  the 
slight  dependence  of  the  U.S.S.R.  on  inland  waterways  is  suggested  by 
the  fact  that  while  nearly  70,000  miles  are  classed  as  navigable  compared 
with  77,000  miles  of  railway,  85  per  cent  of  the  freight  traffic  is  carried 
by  rail.6 

The  U.S.S.R.  has  a  short  coast  line  in  relation  to  its  area,  and  only  a 
few  year-round  ice-free  seaports.  This,  and  the  lack  of  overseas  posses- 
sions, account  for  the  traditional  lack  of  interest  in  foreign  trade  and 
shipping. 

A  large  part  of  the  land  area  of  the  U.S.S.R.  is  not  suitable  for  agricul- 
ture. The  tundra  in  the  north  is  the  area  of  permanently  frozen  subsoil; 
in  the  summer  the  ground  is  swampy.  This  land  is  inhabited  by  a  few 
Lapps  and  Samoyedes  with  their  reindeer.  In  the  south,  around  the  Cas- 
pian Sea  and  throughout  Soviet  Central  Asia,  the  land  is  mostly  desert, 
arable  only  where  water  is  available  for  irrigation.  Southern  Russia,  the 
Ukraine,  and  parts  of  Siberia,  however,  are  famous  for  their  rich  black 
soil  which  is  ideal  for  growing  wheat,  while  the  immense  belt  of  conifer- 

5  The  following  discussion  is  limited  to  such  geographical  factors  as  explain  the 
functional  features  of  the  Soviet  economy  as  a  whole,  and  are  therefore  not  meant  as 
a  substitute  for  a  study  of  the  country's  geography  in  its  many  ramifications.  For  this 
purpose  see  especially  T.  Shabad,  The  Geography  of  the  U.S.S.R.:  A  Regional  Survey 
(New  York,  1951),  and  the  bibliography  on  pp.  3-82. 

G  Stamp  and  Gilmour,  op.  cit.,  p.  509;  also  Trends  in  Economic  Growth,  A  Com- 
parison of  the  Western  Powers  and  the  Soviet  Rloc,  prepared  by  the  Legislative  Refer- 
ence Service  of  the  Library  of  Congress,  1955  (hereafter  referred  to  as  Trends  in 
Economic  Growth),  p.  164. 


474       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

ous  forests,  stretching  across  the  U.S.S.R.  from  the  Gulf  of  Finland  to  the 
Pacific  Ocean,  contains  the  largest  stand  of  virgin  softwood  in  the  world. 
Thirty-four  per  cent  of  the  land  area  of  the  U.S.SJR.  is  occupied  by 
forest,  31  per  cent  by  nonarable  land,  11  per  cent  by  pasture,  and  only 
9  per  cent  by  arable  land.  The  country  is  so  large,  however,  that  this  9  per 
cent  contains  500  million  acres,  compared  with  353  million  acres  under 
cultivation  in  the  United  States  in  1945. 7  On  the  other  hand,  even  where 
the  Soviet  land  can  be  utilized,  the  climate  makes  it  difficult.  Extremely 
severe  winter  weather  is  encountered  throughout  the  north  and  center, 
moderating  slightly  in  the  south  and  southwest.  There  is  hardly  a  place 
in  the  whole  of  the  U.S.S.R.  which  has  an  average  January  temperature 
above  freezing.  Lumbering  is  hampered,  livestock  must  be  sheltered,  and 
even  in  the  great  cultivated  black  earth  belt  the  winters  are  too  severe 
for  fall  planting  of  wheat.  Only  the  production  of  furs  in  the  northern 
forests  seems  to  be  favored  by  climate. 

PEOPLE 

The  population  of  the  present  U.S.S.R.  is  large  and  growing.8  The  cen- 
sus for  1897  shows  a  total  population  of  125.6  million,  that  for  1926,  147 
million,  and  the  population  total  in  1955  can  be  estimated  at  217  million. 
In  1926  almost  82  per  cent  of  the  labor  force  was  agricultural.  Imperial 
Russia  was  predominantly  an  agricultural  country.  Serfdom  was  not  abol- 
ished until  1861,  and  in  the  beginning  of  the  twentieth  century  most  of 
the  peasants  were  uneducated  and  unskilled.  After  the  revolution,  since 
the  principal  economic  goal  of  the  new  regime  was  industrialization,  there 
were  two  main  problems.  One  was  to  find  labor  for  the  growing  new 
industries,  the  other  was  to  bring  twentieth-century  skills  and  technologies 
to  the  labor  force,  both  industrial  and  agricultural.  The  growth  of  Soviet 
population  was  of  some  help  in  solving  the  first  problem  but  not  as  much 
as  might  have  been  expected.9  The  average  rate  of  population  increase 
from  1928  to  1939  was  only  about  2  millions  or  1.2  per  cent  as  compared 
with  2.5  millions  or  1.8  per  cent  over  the  period  1900  to  1914.  This  was 
the  period  roughly  of  the  first  and  second  five-year  plans,  in  which  the 
attendant  social  and  cultural  upheavals  depressed  the  birth  rate  and 
raised  the  death  rate.  Again  population  growth  was  retarded  in  the  war 
period,  1939  to  1950,  the  effects  of  the  war  on  mortality  and  natality  more 

7  Stamp  and  Gilmour,  op.  cit.,  p.  505. 

8  See  pp.  312,  315-316. 

9  W.  W.  Eason,  "Population  and  Labor  Force,"  in  A.  Bergson,  ed.,  Soviet  Economy 
Growth  (Evanston,  1953),  pp.  102  and  103. 


GROWING  ECONOMIC  STRENGTH  OF  SINO-SOVIET  BLOC     475 

than  cancelling  the  "normal"  population  increase.  However,  territorial 
acquisitions  added  some  twenty  million  persons  to  the  Soviet  population. 
As  a  result  the  total  population,  which  stood  at  147  million  in  1926,  in- 
creased to  170.5  million  in  1939  and  was  in  the  neighborhood  of  200  mil- 
lion in  1950. 

However,  during  1926  to  1939,  when  the  total  population  increased  by 
about  twenty-three  million  persons,  the  total  labor  force  increased  by  only 
about  five  million  persons  due  to  the  rise  in  school  attendance  and  the  loss 
of  females  from  the  labor  force  which  accompanied  the  migration  of 
people  from  the  farms.  On  balance,  twenty-five  million  persons  migrated 
from  rural  to  urban  areas  in  the  period  1926  to  1939  and  in  January,  1939, 
the  urban  population  of  the  U.S.S.R.  was  more  than  twice  as  great  as  it 
had  been  in  1926.10  This  movement  was  reflected  in  a  marked  increase  in 
the  nonagricultural  labor  force  at  the  expense  of  the  agricultural  labor 
force.  The  total  labor  force  is  estimated  to  have  been  between  108.4  mil- 
lion and  115.5  million  in  1950.  The  division  of  this  labor  force  between 
agricultural  and  nonagricultural  labor  is  not  known  but  nonagricultural 
workers  were  at  least  35  per  cent  of  the  total,  as  against  18  per  cent  in 
1926.  Projections  of  Soviet  population  to  1970  range  from  244  million  to 
282  million,  with  the  labor  force  increasing  to  between  135  million  and 
160  million.11 

NATURAL  RESOURCES 

One  would  expect  an  area  so  vast  as  the  U.S.S.R.  to  be  liberally  en- 
dowed with  natural  resources  and  this  is  in  fact  the  case  12  (Figs.  15-1,  2). 
Mention  has  already  been  made  of  the  great  forests  and  the  vast  belt  of 
black  earth  lands  of  steppes  or  prairies.  These  have  permitted  the  U.S.S.R. 
to  export  considerable  quantities  of  timber  and  wheat.  The  U.S.S.R.  is  the 
world's  second  largest  cotton  producer  but  exported  only  minor  quantities 
before  World  War  II.  At  present  low  levels  of  domestic  consumption  the 
U.S.S.R.  can  meet  its  own  needs  and  those  of  the  Eastern  European  Satel- 
lites. However,  the  U.S.S.R  is  a  net  importer  of  wool  and  has  no  produc- 
tion of  cacao,  coffee,  jute,  and  rubber. 

In  minerals  and  energy  supply  the  Soviet  Union  equals  or  surpasses  the 
United  States  in  the  variety  and  adequacy  of  its  resources.  The  U.S.S.R. 
is  estimated  to  possess  about  23  per  cent  of  the  world's  known  supply  of 

10  F.  Lorimer,  "Population  Movements  in  Imperial  Russia  and  in  the  Soviet  Union," 
in  H.  W.  Weigert  and  V  Stefansson,  eds.,  Compass  of  the  World  (New  York,  1945), 
pp.  443-460  (449). 

11  Eason,  op.  cit.,  pp.  116-122,  and  below,  pp.  483  ff. 

12  H.  Schwartz,  Russia's  Soviet  Economij,  2nd  ed.  (New  York,  1954),  Ch.  1. 


Fig.  15-1.  Railroads,  Resources,  and  Industrial  Concentrations  in  European  Soviet 
Union:  (1)  industrial  areas;  (2)  coal;  (3)  lignite  coals;  (4)  iron  ore;  (5)  petro- 
leum; (6)  selected  railroads. 

476 


GROWING  ECONOMIC  STRENGTH  OF  SINO-SOVIET  BLOC     477 

inanimate  energy,  more  than  all  the  rest  of  Europe  and  Asia  combined 
(19  per  cent)  and  almost  as  much  as  the  United  States  (29  per  cent). 
This  superiority  is  due  mainly  to  coal  of  which  the  reserves  are  estimated 
at  19  per  cent  of  the  world's  total,  compared  with  49  per  cent  for  the 
United  States  and  Canada,  and  34  per  cent  for  the  rest  of  the  world.13 
Production  of  coal  in  the  U.S.S.R.  increased  very  rapidly  under  the  five- 
year  plans,  from  40  million  tons  in  1929  to  281  million  tons  in  1951.  While 
the  U.S.S.R.  is  now  apparently  the  second  largest  coal  producer  in  the 
world,  the  output  of  coal  has  barely  kept  up  with  the  increasing  demands 
of  industry  and  transportation.14 

In  contrast,  the  importance  of  the  Soviet  Union  as  a  producer  of  petro- 
leum has  declined.  Although  production  had  increased  to  37.9  million  tons 
in  1950,  the  fuel  value  of  petroleum  in  the  U.S.S.R.  had  fallen  from  equal- 
ity with  coal  in  1900  to  less  than  one-fourth,  and  output  in  relation  to  total 
world  production  from  about  50  per  cent  in  1901  to  about  7  per  cent  in 
1950.  The  bulk  of  Soviet  petroleum  output  comes  from  Azerbaidzhan 
(Baku)  (cf.  Fig.  15-1),  and  failure  of  this  and  other  large  fields  to  expand 
more  rapidly  is  attributed  to  failure  to  obtain  maximum  output  from  small 
"pumping"  wells,  and  to  inadequate  exploration  and  development  of  new 
fields.  Moreover  the  geographical  concentration  of  Soviet  oil  output  in  the 
Baku-Maikop-Grozny  triangle  between  the  Black  and  Caspian  Seas,  plus 
the  fact  that  40  per  cent  of  the  petroleum  transported  in  the  U.S.S.R. 
moves  by  rail,  has  put  a  further  strain  on  Soviet  transportation  facilities.15 
However,  petroleum  requirements  are  still  relatively  small  due  to  the  low 
use  of  motor  vehicles,  and  the  U.S.S.R.  has  been  able  to  export  between 
5  and  10  per  cent  of  its  annual  production. 

Water  power,  contrary  to  the  popular  impression,  is  not  highly  devel- 
oped in  the  Soviet  Union.  While  the  potential  production  of  hydro-electric 
power  in  the  U.S.S.R.  is  twice  that  of  the  United  States,  actual  output  in 
1937  was  only  one-tenth  that  of  the  United  States,  and  only  about  one 
per  cent  of  the  potential  yield.  Peat  and  fuel  wood  are  important  sources 
of  fuel  for  industry  and  thermal  stations. 

The  distribution  of  energy  resources  in  the  U.S.S.R.  is  poor,  nearly  90 
per  cent  of  both  coal  and  water  power  being  in  the  relatively  unpopulated 
Asian  part  of  the  U.S.S.R.  (cf.  Fig.  15-2).  Moreover,  much  of  the  coal, 
especially  from  the  more  accessible  mines,  is  of  poor  quality  and  there- 
fore uneconomical  to  transport  over  great  distances.  Water  power  utiliza- 

13  Woytinsky,  op.  cit.,  p.  855. 

14  New  York  Times,  March  6,  1955. 

15  Schwartz,  Russia's  Soviet  Economy,  pp.  234-40;  also,  New  York  Times,  Novem- 
ber 2,  1954,  "Baku  Oil  Output  in  Sharp  Decline." 


•3    2 


478 


GROWING  ECONOMIC  STRENGTH  OF  SINO-SOVIET  RLOC     479 

tion  is  also  hampered  by  freezing  and  uneven  stream  flow.  However, 
planned  goals  for  electricity  and  coal  output  aim  at  equaling  the  present 
output  of  the  United  States  within  a  decade.  These  goals  can  be  fulfilled 
only  through  a  vast  increase  in  the  utilization  of  coal  and  water  power 
resources  in  Soviet  Asia.  According  to  the  Soviet  journal,  Problems  of  Eco- 
nomics,16 almost  half  of  the  U.S.S.R.'s  coal  production  in  1954  originated 
in  its  eastern  areas  and  it  is  expected  that  the  proportion  will  rise  as  new 
sources  are  exploited  in  Soviet  Asia.  Similarly,  the  construction  of  future 
hydro-electric  stations  will  be  concentrated  in  eastern  and  western  Siberia, 
particularly  on  the  Angara,  Yenisei,  and  Ob  rivers. 

The  Soviet  reserve  position  with  regard  to  other  minerals  is  very  good, 
although  extraction  and  processing  seems  to  have  had  difficulty  keeping 
up  with  expansion.17  Before  World  War  II  the  U.S.S.R.  exported  a  number 
of  minerals  including  petroleum,  coal,  iron  ore,  manganese,  platinum, 
phosphates,  and  asbestos,  while  importing  substantial  quantities  of  non- 
ferrous  metals  and  iron  and  steel  for  industrial  expansion.  Imports  of  tin, 
nickel,  tungsten,  molybdenum,  and  lead  were  stockpiled  in  increasing 
amounts.  Nevertheless,  on  balance,  mineral  exports  exceeded  imports. 
During  World  War  II  the  German  armies  overran  most  of  the  mineral- 
producing  areas  and  the  U.S.S.R.  relied  very  heavily  on  Lend-Lease  im- 
ports. 

Since  the  war,  because  of  the  rapid  increase  in  Soviet  consumption  of 
minerals,  and  perhaps  because  of  stockpiling,  the  U.S.S.R.  seems  to  have 
become  a  net  importer  of  minerals.  Principal  mineral  imports  have  been 
coal,  uranium,  zinc,  cadmium,  lead,  arsenic,  barite,  bromine,  fluor  spar, 
and  potash.  It  is  important  to  note,  however,  that  imports  of  these  minerals 
have  come  largely  from  the  European  satellite  countries,  Poland  and  East 
Germany.  Other  important  sources  of  mineral  imports  within  the  Soviet 
bloc  are  Manchuria  and  North  Korea  (pig  iron,  tungsten,  molybdenum, 
lead,  and  zinc )  and  China  ( tungsten,  tin,  and  antimony ) . 

In  brief,  the  minerals  position  of  the  U.S.S.R.  is  one  of  very  large  known 
reserves  of  most  of  the  ferrous  metals,  fuels,  and  non-metallic  minerals, 
with  deficiencies  in  non-ferrous  metals  to  some  extent  compensated  for 
by  availabilities  in  other  parts  of  the  Sino-Soviet  bloc.  Iron  ore  reserves 
are  ample,  although  the  prospect  is  one  of  increasing  pig  iron  costs  due  to 
more  extensive  utilization  of  lower  grade  deposits.18  Manganese  and 
chromium  are  available  for  export.  Evident  deficiencies  of  the  U.S.S.R. 

16  H.  Schwartz,  New  York  Times,  September  25,  1955. 

17  See  D.  Shimkin's  comprehensive  study,  Minerals,  A  Key  To  Soviet  Power  ( Cam- 
bridge, 1953 ) ,  especially  Ch.  9. 

"  Ibid.,  pp.  303,  304-345. 


480       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

include  copper,  nickel,  cobalt,  diamonds,  lead,  molybdenum,  uranium, 
tungsten,  and  zinc.  Satellite  sources  are  capable  of  reducing  or  eliminat- 
ing the  inadequacies  in  lead,  molybdenum,  uranium,  tungsten,  and  zinc.19 
The  ascertained  over-all  position  is  about  as  good  as  that  of  the  United 
States,  and  considering  that  the  U.S.S.R.  is  still  in  the  pioneering  stage  of 
geological  exploration  while  the  United  States  is  far  advanced,  the  poten- 
tial minerals  position  of  the  U.S.S.R.— and  particularly  of  the  Sino-Soviet 
bloc  as  a  whole— is  probably  somewhat  better. 

The  foregoing  description  has  given  us  a  bird's-eye  view  of  the  materials 
from  which  the  Soviet  planners  are  attempting  to  fashion  an  industrial 
base  to  support  the  political  and  military  ambitions  of  the  Kremlin:  a  vast 
area  with  a  harsh  climate,  enormous  distances  to  be  overcome  ( and  there- 
fore a  high  proportion  of  productive  effort  expended  on  transportation), 
a  growing  population  and  an  increasingly  skillful  labor  force,  tremendous 
supplies  of  timber  and  coal,  the  former  hard  to  get  at,  the  latter  poorly 
distributed,  adequate  reserves  of  iron  ore,  and  a  minerals  position  on  the 
whole  better  than  that  of  any  other  world  power  except  the  United  States. 
What  use  are  the  Communists  making  of  these  resources  to  develop  the 
U.S.S.R.'s  economic  capabilities? 

THE  SOVIET  ECONOMY 

The  expansion  of  the  industrial  economy  of  the  U.S.S.R.  under  the  suc- 
cessive five-year  Plans  is  remarkable.  Soviet  official  estimates,  claiming 
a  16  per  cent  annual  average  rate  of  increase  in  national  income  in  the 
period  1928  to  1937,  a  19  per  cent  rate  of  growth  in  1948  to  1950,  and  12 
per  cent  for  1950  to  1951  are  unreliable.  But  even  estimates  by  non-Soviet 
statisticians  credit  the  Soviet  Union  with  rates  of  growth  in  national  in- 
come ranging  from  4.5  per  cent  annually  to  8  or  9  per  cent  for  the  period 
1928  to  1937,  and  a  comparable  rate  of  expansion  during  the  period  1948 
to  1950. 20  Rates  of  growth  in  industrial  production  are  conceded  to  be 
higher  than  for  national  income  because  of  the  priority  given  to  heavy 
industry.  Official  figures  show  an  annual  rate  of  growth  of  20.9  per  cent 
for  1927/28  to  1937  and  23  per  cent  for  1946  to  1950,  but  Western  authori- 
ties similarly  believe  these  claims  are  exaggerated.  The  following  table 
compares  the  official  index  of  industrial  production  in  the  U.S.S.R.  with 
recent  estimates. 

19  Bergson,  op.  cit.,  p.  177. 

20  Ibid.,  p.  9. 


GROWING  ECONOMIC  STRENGTH  OF  SINO-SOVIET  BLOC     481 

TABLE  15-1 

Average  Annual  Percentage  Rates  of  Growth  in  Soviet 
Industrial  Production  ° 


YEARS 

OFFICIAL  INDEX 

REVISED  INDEX 

1927/28 

23.6 

14.5 

1932-37 

18.7 

16.6 

1927/28-1937 

20.9 

15.7 

1937-40 

11.6 

4.7 

1946-50 

23.0 

20.5 

1927/28-1950 

12.5 

8.9 

*  A.  Bergson,  ed.,  Soviet  Economic  Growth   (Evanston,   1953),  p.   242. 

Practically  no  statistics  of  physical  volume  of  output  of  any  commodities 
have  been  published  by  the  Soviet  Union  since  the  late  thirties,  the  only 
direct  sources  of  information  on  production  being  the  official  indices, 
statements  of  plan  fulfillment  and  percentage  increases  over  previous 
years.  However,  by  various  statistical  techniques,  the  following  indices 
have  been  constructed  of  industrial  production  in  the  U.S.S.R.,  and  for 
related  sectors  of  the  economy. 

TABLE   15-2 

U.S.S.R.:   Industry,  Mining,  and  Transportation  * 
(1928=  100) 


100 
184 
363 
422 
337 
615 

a  1927-28. 

*  D.  Hodgeman,  Soviet  Industrial  Production  1928-51   (Cambridge,  1954),  p.  91. 

Different  rates  of  growth  in  the  Soviet  economy  are  shown  in  the  table 
giving  Soviet  net  national  product  by  industrial  origin:  agriculture  in  1953 
showed  little  or  no  increase  over  1937,  while  industry  and  transportation 
more  than  doubled. 

From  1928  to  1951  coal  production  in  the  U.S.S.R.  increased  from  35.5 
million  metric  tons  to  282  million  metric  tons;  crude  oil  production  from 
11.5  million  metric  tons  to  42.3  million  metric  tons,  electric  power  output 
from  5  million  kilowatt  hours  to  102.9  billion  kilowatt  hours,  pig  iron  pro- 


YEARS 

IND.  PROD. 

MINERALS  CON 

1928 

100 a 

100 

1932 

172 

171 

1937 

371 

357 

1940 

430 

400 

1946 

304 

386 

1950 

646 

586 

482       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

duction  from  3.3  million  metric  tons  to  22.1  million  metric  tons,  crude  steel 
production  from  4.2  million  metric  tons  to  31.4  million  metric  tons,  and 
passenger  cars  and  trucks  from  600  or  700  to  364,000.  By  1950,  U.S.S.R. 
coal  output  was  52  per  cent  of  that  of  the  United  States,  steel  production 
31  per  cent,  electric  power  23  per  cent,  cement  production  27  per  cent 
and  woven  cotton  and  woolen  fabrics  40  to  45  per  cent.  "In  the  short  span 
of  thirty  years,  the  Soviet  Union  has  risen  from  the  ranks  to  become  the 
second  most  powerful  industrial  nation  in  the  world."  21 

TABLE   15-3 
The  Soviet  Net  National  Product,  1937-53  * 


1937 

1948 

1953 

INDUSTRY 

(1) 

(2) 

(1) 

(2) 

(1) 

(2) 

Agriculture  (3) 
Industry  (4) 
Transportation  & 

Communications 
Civil   and   military  services 

Total  gross  national 
Product 

36 
34 

7 
22 

100 
100 

100 
100 

28 
36 

8 
28 

86 
121 

120 
142 

23 
46 

10 
21 

102 
221 

211 

155 

100 

100 

100 

113 

100 

162 

(1)  Percentage  of  gross  national   product   in   that   year,   measured   in    1937    factor   costs    (Bergson),   ad- 
justed for  higher  estimates  of  imputed  land  rents. 

(2)  Index,  1937  —  100,  in  same  measure. 

(3)  Includes  imputed  land  rentals. 

(4)  Includes    manufacturing,    handicrafts,    mining,    forestry,    and    fisheries    (Soviet    definition    of    "In- 
dustry"), plus  construction. 

*  H.   Block  in   Trends  in  Economic  Growth,  p.   284. 

A  large  part  of  the  increased  output  in  the  U.S.S.R.  has  taken  the  form 
of  investment  in  capital  goods  and  production  for  military  purposes  rather 
than  increased  foodstuffs  and  other  goods  for  consumption.  Consequently, 
the  record  of  production  in  the  latter  sectors  is  not  too  impressive.  A  care- 
fully constructed  index  of  consumer  goods  production  gives  a  figure  of  258 
for  1950  (1928  =  100),  compared  with  646  for  all  large-scale  (heavy) 
industrial  production.  Per  capita  production  of  consumer  goods  in  1950 
was  less  than  twice  that  of  1928  because  of  the  intervening  growth  in 
population.22  Soviet  gross  agricultural  production  in  1940  was  only  15  per 
cent  above  1927-28  when  the  collective  and  state  farm  programs  were 
started,  and  by  1950  had  risen  by  no  more  than  a  further  10  per  cent  of 
1940  output.23 

21  Hodgeman,  op.  cit.,  Table  A  and  pp.  128-130. 

22  Ibid.,  p.  128. 

23  V.  Timoshenko,  "Agriculture  in  the  Soviet  Spotlight,"  Foreign  Affairs  (January, 
1954),  pp.  244-258. 


GROWING  ECONOMIC  STRENGTH  OF  SINO-SOVIET  BLOC     483 

This  lopsided  development  of  the  Soviet  economy  is  due,  on  the  one 
hand,  to  the  deliberate  concentration  on  heavy  industry  in  Soviet  eco- 
nomic planning  and,  on  the  other,  to  both  physical  and  institutional  ob- 
stacles to  the  expansion  of  Soviet  agricultural  production  which  will  be 
discussed  later. 


FACTORS  IN  SOVIET  ECONOMIC  GROWTH 

The  unusual  growth  of  the  Soviet  economy  since  the  1930's  seems  to  be 
due  to  institutional  factors  rather  than  to  any  favorable  combination  of 
physical  factors  and  technology.  This  is  suggested  by  the  relatively  slow 
progress  of  the  Russian  economy  prior  to  the  revolution  and  is  confirmed 
by  an  analysis  of  the  events  that  followed. 

The  most  important  factor  was  the  decision  of  the  Communist  rulers 
to  subordinate  everything  to  the  expansion  of  Soviet  industry,  a  decision 
motivated  by  Marxist  doctrine  and  made  possible  by  the  conditions  of 
totalitarian  rule.  The  mobilization  of  resources  for  investment  in  heavv 

J 

industry  was  literally  decreed  and  enforced  by  the  state,  while  consump- 
tion was  drastically  restricted  by  wage  control,  rationing,  and  the  sheer 
non-availability  of  many  consumer  goods.  The  high  priority  afforded  to 
heavy  industry  and  transport  from  the  beginning  accounts  for  the  high 
rate  of  growth  in  the  late  thirties  and  late  forties  as  the  process  began  to 
pay  dividends  in  output. 

Second  in  importance  was  the  fact  that  the  new  industrial  technology 
had  already  been  developed  abroad  and  could  readily  be  copied  by  im- 
porting technicians,  prototypes,  and  plans.  A  large  part  of  the  high  growth 
rate  of  the  Soviet  economy  is  explainable  in  terms  of  this  process  of  catch- 
ing up  with  the  highly  industrialized  states  of  the  West. 

In  analytical  terms,  the  expansion  of  output  in  the  U.S.S.R.  can  be  at- 
tributed to  ( 1 )  an  expansion  in  the  total  labor  force,  ( 2 )  an  increase  in 
labor  productivity,  and  (3)  a  shift  in  employment  of  labor  from  occupa- 
tions of  lower  to  those  of  higher  marginal  productivity.  We  have  referred 
above  to  the  growth  of  the  labor  force.  Labor  productivity  in  the  U.S.S.R. 
also  increased  markedly,  although  by  not  nearly  enough  to  explain  the 
large  increases  in  output.  The  most  important  component  in  the  increase 
in  Soviet  product  during  the  period  1928  to  1937  appears  to  have  been  the 
shift  of  labor  from  agricultural  to  nonagricultural  employments  where 
marginal  productivity  was  higher,24  a  transfer  which  increased  the  non- 
agricultural  labor  force,  on  the  average,  by  about  10  per  cent  annually 

?4  Q.  Grossman,  "National  Income,"  Ch.  1  in  Bergson,  op.  cit.,  pp.  13,  14. 


484        THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

during  this  period.  Increasing  labor  productivity  appears  to  have  been 
more  important  in  the  late  thirties  and  in  the  postwar  period. 

In  many  respects  the  physical  and  geographical  factors  seemed  to  hin- 
der rather  than  aid  the  expansion  of  the  Soviet  economy.  Mention  has 
already  been  made  of  the  relatively  slow  rate  of  growth  in  petroleum 
production,  and  exploitation  of  other  mineral  resources  has  apparently 
run  into  increasing  production  costs  and  unfavorable  geographical  distri- 
bution of  resources.  The  vastness  of  the  land  area  and  the  distances  to  be 
traversed  by  the  transportation  system  in  the  U.S.S.R.  posed  major  prob- 
lems (cf.  Figs.  15-1,  2,  pp.  476,  478).  As  Chauncy  Harris  put  it: 

The  negative  economic  role  of  the  area  looms  even  larger  when  one  considers 
the  human  emptiness  of  most  of  it.  Most  of  the  people  of  the  Soviet  Union  live 
in  what  is  called  the  Fertile  Triangle  with  its  corners  at  Leningrad  on  a  gulf  of 
the  Baltic  Sea,  at  Odessa  on  the  Black  Sea,  and  at  the  Kuznetsk  Basin  in  Siberia. 
The  Triangle  includes  about  one  million  square  miles,  an  area  roughly  equiva- 
lent to  the  United  States  east  of  the  Mississippi  River.  With  the  exception  of  the 
Caucasus  and  the  oases  of  Central  Asia  most  of  the  rest  of  the  Soviet  Union  is 
relatively  bare  space  which  must  be  crossed  by  long  transport  lines.25 

This  factor,  plus  the  heavy  reliance  on  solid  instead  of  liquid  fuel,  has 
greatly  increased  the  share  of  resources  that  have  to  be  devoted  to  trans- 
portation. The  Soviet  transport  co-efficient  (percentage  of  total  output 
devoted  to  transportation)  is  the  highest  in  the  world  and  40  per  cent 
higher  than  in  the  United  States.26  This  is  readily  seen  from  a  comparison 
of  ton-miles  of  freight  carried,  for  example  in  1953:  605  billion  ton  miles 
for  the  United  States  and  538  billion  for  the  U.S.S.R.  with  less  than  one- 
third  the  gross  national  product.27  In  the  twenties,  Soviet  planners  resisted 
the  need  to  expand  the  rail  and  other  transportation  systems  because  of 
a  doctrinaire  notion  that  transportation  represented  an  unproductive  ac- 
tivity. When  this  neglect  threatened  a  breakdown  in  industrial  activity, 
a  more  energetic  policy  was  adopted,  both  with  regard  to  the  expansion 
of  the  system  and  the  efficiency  of  operations.28  However,  the  desire  to 
minimize  the  resources  allocated  to  transportation  conflicted  with  the 
need  to  develop  outlying  areas  containing  untapped  resources.  The  result 
was  a  decision  to  locate  industrial  development  in  five  relatively  concen- 
trated and  more  or  less  self-sufficient  regions.29  Official  theory  does  not 

25  Ibid.,  p.  164. 

26  D.  Shimkin,  quoted  in  Trends  in  Economic  Growth,  p.  165. 

27  Trends  in  Economic  Growth,  Table  60,  p.  171. 

28  Schwartz,  Russia's  Soviet  Economy,  pp.  389-404.  The  basic  work  in  this  field  is 
H.  Hunter's  The  Economics  of  Soviet  Railroad  Policy   (Cambridge,  Mass.,   1949). 

2  9  See  Fig.  14-3,  p.  468. 


GROWING  ECONOMIC  STRENGTH  OF  SINO-SOVIET  BLOC     485 

appear  to  recognize  that  such  a  policy  may  tend  to  retard  the  over-all 
growth  of  output  by  limiting  opportunities  to  reduce  costs  through  a  wider 
geographical  division  of  labor.30  The  future  expansion  of  Soviet  railroads 
will  depend  on  whether  these  policies  of  regional  self-sufficiency  and 
equalization  remain  in  force.  If  they  do  not,  there  will  be  a  greater  need 
for  interregional  rail  transportation.  In  a  speech  delivered  in  April,  1954, 
First  Deputy  Premier  Kaganovich  admitted  that  the  regional  self-suffi- 
ciency policies  were  being  ignored  and  cross-hauling  was  occurring  on  a 
large  scale  because  nobody  "cared  where  goods  are  coming  from  or  asked 
about  transport  costs.  .  .  .  They  are  all  only  interested  in  getting  the  goods 
at  all."31 

If  all  Soviet  railway  construction  were  regulated  exclusively  by  Soviet 
economic  location  theory,  the  result  would  be  a  railway  system  con- 
structed without  regard  to  strategic  requirements.  While  Soviet  planners 
have  perhaps  not  constructed  exactly  the  kind  of  railway  system  Halford 
Mackinder  would  have  expected,  they  have  evidently  taken  strategic  fac- 
tors into  account,  as  in  the  double-tracking  of  the  trans-Siberian  over  its 
entire  distance,  the  construction  of  the  south  trans-Siberian,  and  the  re- 
ported construction  of  the  Baikal-Amur  (northern  trans-Siberian)  road. 
Another  departure  from  the  orthodox  location  theory  may  be  evident  in 
a  program  for  construction  of  an  entirely  new  rail  network  in  southwestern 
Siberia  to  handle  grain  produced  under  the  new  "conquest  of  virgin 
lands"  program  to  increase  agricultural  output  and  food  supplies  for  the 
urban  population.32 

SOVIET  FOREIGN  TRADE 

Soviet  economic  policy  has  always  aimed  at  eventual  autarky  (self- 
sufficiency).  Nevertheless  imports  played  an  important  part  in  accelerat- 
ing the  rate  of  industrialization  especially  during  the  thirties.  A  brief 
discussion  of  the  role  of  foreign  trade  is  necessary  to  an  understanding  of 
the  economic  capabilities  of  the  Soviet  bloc. 

Soviet  foreign  trade  policy,  as  explained  in  1934  to  the  Seventeenth 
Party  Congress  by  Foreign  Trade  Commissar  Rozengoltz,  "meant  that  by 

30  For  a  further  examination  of  this  point  see  Bergson,  op.  cit.,  p.  158,  comments 
by  H.  Hunter  on  J.  Blackman's  paper  on  "Soviet  Transportation"  (Ch.  4);  also 
D.  Shimkin,  "Economic  Regionalization  in  the  Soviet  Union,"  Geographical  Revieio, 
Vol.  42  (October,  1952),  pp.  596-614;  also  Schwartz,  op.  cit.,  p.  400. 

31  Schwartz,  Russia's  Soviet  Economy,  p.  403;  also  The  Tablet  (London,  September 
4,  1954),  pp.  222-223. 

32  T.  Shabad,  "Soviet  Adds  Rails  in  New  Grain  Area,"  New  York  Times,  May  15, 
1955. 


486       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

extending  our  economic  contact  with  the  capitalist  world  and  introducing 
the  latest  technical  innovations  and  speeding  up  our  socialist  construction 
by  means  of  considerable  imports  over  a  definite  period  of  time,  we  should 
prepare  for  the  next  stage— the  continuation  of  socialist  construction  on 
the  basis  of  a  contraction  of  imports."  33 

Foreign  trade  of  the  U.S.S.R.  expanded  from  virtually  nothing  in  the 
first  two  or  three  years  after  the  revolution  to  a  peak  in  the  late  twenties 
and  early  thirties  when  the  U.S.S.R.,  embarked  on  its  first  five-year  plan 
of  rapid  industrialization,  was  desperately  demanding  imported  capital 
goods.  Foodstuffs  (despite  widespread  famine  in  the  Ukraine),  timber, 
petroleum,  and  industrial  raw  materials  were  exchanged  for  producers' 
goods  (machinery  and  equipment),  on  terms  that  became  distinctly  un- 
favorable to  the  U.S.S.R.  because  the  world-wide  depression  affected 
prices  of  raw  materials  much  more  than  the  prices  of  finished  goods.  After 
1931  the  volume  of  foreign  trade  fell  off  and  by  1940  the  Ministry  of  For- 
eign trade  was  congratulating  itself  on  the  fact  that  the  U.S.S.R.  ranked 
second  in  industrial  production  and  nineteenth  in  foreign  trade.34  At  that 
time  the  Soviet  economist  Mishustin  reiterated  that  Soviet  foreign  trade 
policy  was  "to  utilize  foreign  products  and  above  all  foreign  machinery 
.  .  .  for  the  technical  and  economic  independence  of  the  U.S.S.R.  . .  .The 
speediest  liberation  from  the  need  to  import." 

During  World  War  II  the  liberation  from  imports  was  temporarily  sus- 
pended and  the  U.S.S.R.  received  almost  $13  billion  worth  of  goods,  most 
of  it  from  the  United  States,  under  lend-lease  arrangements.  Lend-lease 
deliveries  averaged  about  $3  billion  annually,  far  greater  than  the  highest 
prewar  level  of  imports  in  1931. 

Analysis  of  the  course  of  Soviet  foreign  trade  in  the  postwar  period  is 
complicated  by  the  paucity  of  data  relating  to  trade  between  the  U.S.S.R. 
and  the  European  satellites  and  China.  In  1953  trade  between  the  Free 
World  and  the  Communist  bloc  as  a  whole  was  only  about  one-third  the 
pre- World  War  II  volume  of  trade  carried  on  between  the  two  sets  of 
countries,  whereas  trade  within  the  Communist  bloc  was  reported  to  be 
ten  times  the  prewar  volume.  The  principal  reason  for  these  differences 
is  that  the  countries  of  Eastern  Europe  before  World  War  II  conducted 
most  of  their  trade  with  Western  Europe.  Since  the  war  their  trade  has 

33  A.  P.  Rozengoltz,  The  USSR  and  the  Capitalist  World  (Moscow,  1934),  p.  4, 
quoted  by  L.  Herman,  "The  New  Soviet  Posture  in  World  Trade,"  Problems  of  Com- 
munism, Vol.  3,  No.  6  (Washington,  D.  C,  1954). 

34  Bakulin  and  Mishustin,  Statistika  Vneshnei  Torgovli  (Moscow,  1940),  p.  299, 
quoted  by  L.  Herman,  op.  cit. 


GROWING  ECONOMIC  STRENGTH  OF  SINO-SOVIET  BLOC     487 

been  forcibly  re-directed  inward,  to  the  U.S.S.R.  and  with  one  another. 
This  is  shown  in  the  following  estimates  of  the  volume  of  intra-bloc  trade 
for  1947  and  1951. 

TABLE   15-4 

Intra-Bloc  Trade  * 
U.S.S.R.  and  Eastern  European  Satellites 


1947  ' 

J  951  a 

U.S.S.R. 

U.S.S.R. 

U.S.S.R. 

U.S.S.R. 

COUNTRY 

IMPORTS 

EXPORTS 

IMPORTS 

EXPORTS 

Albania 

6.5 

6.5 

12.0 

12.0 

Bulgaria 

44.7 

45.6 

66.9 

86.4 

Czechoslovakia 

27.9 

38.9 

222.5 

247,5 

Hungary 

13.4 

14.5 

117.1 

111.2 

Poland 

70.5 

79.5 

190.0 

235.0 

Rumania 

19.9 

29.9 

119.7 

122.5 

E.    Germany 

16.0 

11.0 

176.0 

250.0 

Totals 

198.9 

225.9 

904.2 

1064.6 

a  Millions  of  United  States  dollars. 

*  Estimated  by  Leon   Herman,   given   in   H.   Schwartz,   Russia's  Soviet   Economy,   2nd   ed.    (New   York, 
1954),  pp.  614-615. 

In  1938  these  countries  supplied  the  U.S.S.R.  with  only  $30  million 
of  goods  or  11  per  cent  of  its  total  imports.  In  1952  the  bloc  furnished  over 
$1  billion  of  imports  35  or  almost  70  per  cent  of  total  Soviet  imports.  In 
general  this  trade  consists  of  an  exchange  of  Soviet  manufactured  and 
semi-manufactured  goods  for  satellite  raw  materials  and  foodstuffs.  How- 
ever, East  Germany,  Czechoslovakia,  and  Poland  supply  some  machinery 
and  transport  equipment  and  minerals. 

Trade  between  the  U.S.S.R.  and  the  Free  World  in  the  period  1947  to 
1953  has  fluctuated  between  $300  million  and  $500  million  annually  in 
imports  and  $250  million  to  $500  million  in  exports  ( current  prices ) .  Trade 
between  the  European  satellites  and  the  Free  World  increased  to  $1.1  bil- 
lion in  exports  and  $900  million  in  exports  in  1948  and  1949.  It  declined 
to  about  $800  million  in  exports  and  $700  million  in  imports  in  1953.  The 
satellites  have  had  a  visible  trade  surplus  which,  with  occasional  gold 
sales  has  helped  the  U.S.S.R.  to  balance  its  visible  trade  deficit  with  the 
Free  World.  Details  of  U.S.S.R.  and  bloc  trade  are  given  in  the  following 
table. 

35  Official  statistics  of  Free  World  countries,  compiled  by  the  United  States  De- 
partment of  Commerce. 


488       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

TABLE  15-5 

Soviet  Bloc  Free  World  Trade,  1947-54  * 
(Millions  of  United  States  Dollars  at  Current  Prices) 


1947 

1949 

1953 

Free  World  Exports  to: 

U.S.S.R. 

477 

437 

438 

European   Satellites 

857 

919 

682 

Total 

1,334 

1,356 

1,120 

Free  World  Imports  from: 

U.S.S.R 

271 

272 

385 

European  Satellites 

733 

1,090 

810 

Total 

1,004 

1,362 

1,195 

*  See  footnote  35. 

The  volume  of  this  trade  has  been  limited  not  only  by  the  multilateral 
export  controls  over  "strategic"  commodities  enforced  by  the  principal 
Free  World  trading  countries  operating  through  a  Co-ordinating  Commit- 
tee in  Paris,  but  also  by  the  inability  or  unwillingness  of  the  U.S.S.R.  to 
deliver  its  traditional  exports  of  grain,  timber,  and  raw  materials.  Soviet 
offers  to  sell  capital  goods  on  favorable  credit  terms,  especially  to  under- 
developed countries,  have  been  until  recently  mostly  propaganda  state- 
ments. 

While  the  foreign  (East-West)  trade  that  is  permitted  undoubtedly 
makes  a  contribution  to  Soviet  economic  growth,  its  volume  is  now  too 
small  in  relation  to  Soviet  production  and  national  income  to  make  a  sig- 
nificant difference  in  the  rate  of  this  growth.  The  period  when  foreign 
trade  made  a  vital  and  indispensable  contribution  to  Soviet  economic 
growth  was  in  the  late  twenties  and  the  thirties;  it  is  too  late  now  to 
expect  to  do  much  damage  to  the  Soviet  economy  by  export  controls  or 
other  devices  of  economic  warfare.  The  importance  of  intra-bloc  trade 
is  a  somewhat  different  matter;  although  the  value  of  this  trade  is  roughly 
twice  the  value  of  the  East-West  trade  of  the  European  Soviet 36  bloc  and 
it  may  present  greater  advantages  to  the  U.S.S.R.  because  of  its  perma- 
nence, and  the  much  greater  degree  of  control  the  U.S.S.R.  can  exert  in 
regard  to  prices,  quality,  and  other  considerations.37 

Since  1953  the  Soviet  bloc  has  waged  a  new  campaign  of  economic 
diplomacy  in  non-Communist  underdeveloped  areas  designed  to  increase 

36  Economic  Commission  for  Europe,  Economic  Survey  of  Europe  in  1954  (Geneva, 
1955),  Table  63,  p.  111. 
s^  See  p.  28. 


GROWING  ECONOMIC  STRENGTH  OF  SINO-SOVIET  BLOC     489 

trade  and  other  economic  relations  with  these  areas.  The  principal  ele- 
ments have  been  offers  to  purchase  goods  in  excess  supply  and  to  supply 
credits  and  technical  assistance  for  economic  development.  In  some  cases 
military  equipment  has  been  offered  in  exchange  for  raw  materials  like 
cotton. 

PROSPECTS  FOR  FUTURE  GROWTH 

We  have  seen  that  the  economy  of  the  U.S.S.R.  has  been  characterized 
by  quite  high  rates  of  growth  under  the  various  five-year  plans,  rates  that, 
if  continued,  would  seem  to  make  Stalin's  famous  production  goals  (50 
million  metric  tons  of  pig  iron,  60  million  metric  tons  of  steel,  500  million 
metric  tons  of  coal  and  60  million  metric  tons  of  petroleum)  38  easily 
attainable  by  1960.  A  number  of  factors,  however,  suggest  that  recent 
rates  of  increase  may  not  be  maintained.  Among  these  are  the  recent  indi- 
cations of  a  growing  need  for  more  housing,  consumer  goods,  and  food- 
stuffs. Housing  is  notoriously  poor  in  the  U.S.S.R.  in  terms  both  of  quality 
and  quantity.  Even  to  supply  the  growing  population  over  the  next  sev- 
eral decades  with  sufficient  housing  by  present  standards  will  require 
much  larger  investment  in  housing  than  the  postwar  rate.  Housing  also 
competes  for  some  of  the  same  materials  and  labor  as  investment  in  in- 
dustry. Increased  consumer  goods  means  primarily  more  clothing  made 
from  scarce  fibers,  cotton  and  wool.  To  increase  output  of  these  "technical 
crops"  is  to  add  to  the  agricultural  problem. 

We  have  seen  that  gross  agricultural  production  increased  by  only  23 
per  cent  between  1928  and  1950,  not  enough  to  keep  up  with  population 
growth.  If  a  population  increase  to  260  million  people  by  1970  is  assumed, 
this  would  require  a  30  per  cent  increase  in  output  of  foodstuffs  over  1950 
merely  to  keep  per  capita  consumption  from  falling.  Despite  official  as- 
surances that  heavy  industry  and  transport  will  continue  to  receive  prior- 
ity, it  is  obvious  that  to  increase  per  capita  agricultural  production  will 
require  intensive  efforts  and  probably  a  heavier  investment  than  previ- 
ously, since  during  the  period  1928  to  1950  agriculture  received  an  esti- 
mated 15  to  20  per  cent  of  total  investment  with  no  appreciable  increase 
in  per  capita  output.39 

The  problem  of  expanding  agricultural  output  is  so  crucial  to  the  gen- 
eral outlook  for  the  economy  of  the  U.S.S.R.  that  it  deserves  at  least  a 
brief  examination  here. 

38  Speech  of  February  9,  1946. 

39  N.  Kaplan,  "Capital  Formation  and  Allocation"  in  Bergson,  op.  cit.,  p.  52. 


490       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  E\  POLTTICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

Soviet  agriculture  suffers  from  difficulties  of  an  institutionaL  physical, 
and  economic  character.-  During  the  earlv  thirties  the  Communists  vir- 
tuallv  made  war  on  the  peasants  for  resisting  collectivization.  Agricultural 
production  declined  and  one-half  of  all  the  livestock  were  killed.  There 
were  10  million  fewer  cattle  in  the  U.S.S.R.  in  1953  than  in  192S.  with 
90  per  cent  of  the  decline  being  in  cow; 

After  Stalin's  death,  the  new  regime  promised  better  food  as  well  as 
more  food  to  a  population  that  has  long  been  confined  to  a  diet  of  bread 
and  potatoes.  But  better  food  means  meat,  milk,  and  lard  as  well  as  fruits 
and  vegetables.  Animal  crops  require  several  times  more  land  and  labor 
than  vegetable  food,  and  some  of  the  technical  crops  require  a  subtropical 
climate.  The  area  of  subtropical  climate  is  verv  limited  in  the  U.S.S.R.  and 
most  of  it  is  vers-  drv.  Recent  efforts  to  increase  the  number  of  livestock 
have  failed,  mainlv  because  of  the  scarcitv  of  fodder  but  also  partlv  be- 
cause the  collective  farm  organization  is  not  well  adapted  to  the  intensive 
forms  of  agriculture.  Moreover  until  recentlv  the  remuneration  of  collec- 
tive farm  members  engaging  in  animal  husbandrv  averaged  about  one- 
fourth  of  that  received  for  the  cultivation  of  technical  crops  i  cotton ) . 

Expanding  the  supplv  of  food  grains  comes  up  against  the  fact  that  all 
the  good  arable  land  in  the  U.S.S.R.— according  to  present  technology— is 
already  cultivated,  with  70  per  cent  in  grain  and  with  only  one-third  of 
the  grain  area  devoted  to  feed  grains.  As  a  consequence,  great  emphasis  is 
being  placed  on  increasing  the  acre-vield  of  grain,  and  the  current  five- 
vear  plan  I  1951-55  calls  for  an  increase  of  40  per  cent  an  accomplish- 
ment not  likelv  to  be  realized  in  view  of  past  performance  and  the  fact 
that  1953  and  1954  both  saw  poor  harvests. 

Among  the  measures  that  have  been  adopted  are  Stalin's  Tlan  for  the 
Transformation  of  Nature''  calling  for  extensive  shelter  belts  and  refor- 
estation through  the  European  steppes,  crop  rotation,  and  water  conserva- 
tion, and.  more  recentlv.  Kruschev's  campaign  for  the  "conquest  of  virgin 
land"  calling  for  the  ploughing  of  15  million  hectares  of  new  land  per  vear 
in  1954.  1955.  and  1956.  This  is  calculated  to  provide  60  million  tons  of 
additional  grain  bv  1957.  The  virgin  land  to  be  "conquered"  is  in  the 
northern  Caucasus,  the  Volga  region,  the  Urals,  in  Western  Siberia,  and 
Kazakhstan.  Kazakhstan  has  an  area  of  1.072.797  square  miles,  three 
times  the  size  of  Te  1  7.000  square  miles  .  with  a  population     1939 

of  6-000.000.  of  which  1.700.000  lived  in  cities.  The  "conquest"  will  be  or- 
ganized by  large  state  farms   |  Sovkhoses     rather  than  collective  farms 

!    The  discussion  is  based  largely  on  Timoshenko.  op.  cit. 


GROWING  ECONOMIC  STRENGTH  OF  SINO-SOVIET  BLOC     491 

(kolkhoses),  since  state  farms  can  be  more  easily  set  up  and  controlled. 
According  to  Soviet  claims  41  the  total  sown  area  in  Kazakhstan  was  9  mil- 
lion hectares  in  1954,  and  the  goal  for  1955  was  18.6  million;  for  1956, 
28.5  million  hectares.  There  are  50,000  new  houses  projected  for  1955  and 
100,000  for  1956.  All  these  figures  illustrate  an  undeniably  strong  pressure 
to  bring  new  land  under  the  plough,  especially  in  Kazakhstan  and  West- 
ern Siberia,  in  a  task  which,  if  successful,  would  extend  the  core  areas  of 
Soviet  grain  production  into  Soviet  Asia.  The  goal  is  to  create  a  new 
wheatland  area  with  a  production  to  rival  that  of  the  Ukraine;  an  eastward 
migration  of  "volunteers"  from  Russia  and  the  Ukraine,  and  the  earmark- 
ing of  120,000  tractors  for  this  operation  lend  emphasis  to  this  battle  for 
grain. 

Additional  land  is  also  being  reclaimed  by  four  big  irrigation  projects 
on  the  Dnieper,  the  Volga,  the  Don,  and  the  Amu  Darya  rivers.  These 
projects  are  expected  to  provide  only  about  15  million  acres  for  crops,  but 
about  55  million  acres  of  grazing  lands,  mainly  in  the  arid  and  desert  lands 
north  and  east  of  the  Caspian.  Water  from  the  Volga  must  be  used  spar- 
ingly because  of  the  falling  level  of  the  Caspian  Sea. 

It  remains  to  be  seen  how  effective  these  measures  will  be.  It  would  be 
an  extreme  and  rash  judgment  to  conclude  that  the  problem  of  expanding 
agricultural  output  could  not  be  solved  by  an  economy  whose  accomplish- 
ments in  other  fields  of  output  have  been  so  considerable.  The  likelihood 
is,  however,  that  the  obstacles  to  be  overcome  will  require  not  only  larger 
investments  in  agriculture  but  perhaps  also  greater  incentive  payments  to 
members  of  collective  farms.  In  the  process  the  share  of  output  going  to 
investment  in  industry  might  well  be  noticeably  reduced,  and  the  share  of 
output  represented  by  consumer  goods  increased.  The  net  result  of  such 
developments,  considering  the  lower  average  productivity  in  agriculture, 
would  be  to  reduce  the  over-all  rate  of  growth  of  the  Soviet  economy.  On 
the  other  hand,  higher  standards  of  living  may  help  to  keep  average  in- 
dustrial labor  productivity  up  to  the  1950-53  average  increase  of  4.5  to 
5  per  cent  annually  despite  lower  aggregate  investment.  If  the  productiv- 
ity of  agricultural  labor  could  be  raised  by  the  new  measures  by  about 
3  per  cent  annually,  a  continuation  of  over-all  economic  growth  at  the  rate 
of  about  4.5  to  5  per  cent  is  not  out  of  the  realm  of  probability.  This  would 
mean  roughly  a  doubling  of  national  product  between  1953  and  1970.42 

41  The  Economist,  March  20,  1954,  pp.  873-874;  also  November  3,  1954,  p.  568. 

42  For  the  detailed  derivation  of  this  projection  see  Trends  in  Economic  Growth, 
pp.  219-222. 


492       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

B.    Eastern  Europe — the  Soviet  Satellites 

The  European  satellites  of  the  U.S.S.R.  (cf.  Fig.  5-6,  p.  133)  add  95 
million  people,  and  an  area  of  392,000  square  miles  to  the  mass,  if  not  to 
the  unity  and  power  of  the  Soviet  bloc.  They  comprise  Poland,  Eastern 
Germany,  Czechoslovakia  and  the  Balkan  states:  Hungary,  Rumania,  Bul- 
garia, and  Albania.  Compared  with  Western  Europe,  the  combined  indus- 
trial power  of  these  states  is  not  great  (cf.  Fig.  17-1,  p.  540).  Neverthe- 
less, as  we  have  seen,  the  productive  capacity  of  the  European  satellites  is 
significant  because  it  is  more  or  less  at  the  disposal  of  the  Soviet  planners, 
through  redirection  of  the  satellites'  foreign  trade  as  well  as  by  more  direct 
political  and  administrative  devices,  and  we  must  take  account  of  it  in  any 
assessment  of  the  over-all  capabilities  of  the  Soviet  bloc.  This  is  not  hard 
to  do  in  the  gross,  for  we  have,  by  virtue  of  recent  historical  data,  a  more 
accurate  notion  of  the  main  economic  factors  of  these  countries  than  of 
the  U.S.S.R.  However  there  is  little  statistical  information  available  for  the 
postwar  period  to  indicate  the  precise  patterns  and  levels  of  economic 
activity  in  the  various  countries,  and  the  volume  and  composition  of  their 
trade  with  the  U.S.S.R.  is  likewise  shrouded  in  official  secrecy. 

The  over-all  contribution  of  Eastern  Europe  to  the  economic  capabili- 
ties of  the  Soviet  bloc  is  summarized  in  the  accompanying  table. 

TABLE  15-6 
Economic  Capabilities  (1955)   of  the  European  Satellites* 

UNIT  EUROPEAN  SATELLITES   U.S.S.R. 

Population  Millions 

Gross  Nat.  Product        Billion  dollars 

Per  Capita  Dollars 

Coal  Production  Million  M.T. 

Crude  Steel  Prod.  Million  M.T. 

Electric  Power  Million  KWH 

Crude  Petroleum  Million  M.T. 

*  Dept.  of  State  IR  7247. 

The  greatest  concentration  in  Eastern  Europe  of  industrial  strength, 
as  well  as  of  population,  is  in  Poland,  East  Germany,  and  Czechoslovakia. 
Albania  and  Bulgaria  at  the  other  extreme  are  almost  exclusively  agrarian 
economies  with  a  peasant  culture.  Hungary  and  Rumania  are  also  pre- 
dominantly agricultural,  but  together  produced  about  4.5  million  metric 
tons  of  crude  petroleum  in  1948,  the  last  year  for  which  Rumanian  pro- 
duction data  are  available.  Hungarian  oil  production  was  estimated  at 


95 

217 

50 

149 

526 

687 

218 

330 

14 

45 

74 

170 

15 

71 

GROWING  ECONOMIC  STRENGTH  OF  SINO-SOVIET  RLOC     493 

500,000  tons  in  1952. 4i  The  following  table  shows  some  of  the  differences 
in  the  relative  economic  importance  of  the  various  Eastern  European 
countries. 

TABLE  15-7 
Population  and  Economic  Activity,  Eastern  Europe 


POPULATION 

HARD  COAL  PROD. 

STEEL  PROD. 

ELECTRIC  POWER 

(Millions) 

(Millions  M.T.) 

(Millions  M.T.) 

( Billions  KWH ) 

COUNTRY 

1950  a 

1951 d 

195  rJ 

1951 d 

Poland 

25.0  b 

82.0 

2.8 

11.1 

E.  Germany 

21.0° 

3.2 

1.5 

20.8 

Rumania 

16.3° 

0.3 

0.7 

2.5 

Czechoslovakia 

12.4 

17.9 

3.3 

10.3 

Hungary 

9.4 

1.8 

1.2 

3.3 

Bulgaria 

7.2 

— 

— 

1.0 

Albania 

1.2° 

— 

— 

— 

a  Economic  Commission  For  Europe  (ECE),  Growth  and  Stagnation  in  the  European  Economy  (Geneva, 
19S4),  p.  237. 
b  United  Nations,  Statistical  Year  Book,   1953   (New  York,   1953),  pp.   29-30,   1950  census. 
c  Ibid.,  estimates   for    1952. 
d  ECE,  Economic  Survey  oj  Europe  Since  the  War  (Geneva,  1954),  pp.  244-246. 

Before  World  War  II  foodstuffs  accounted  for  more  than  two-thirds  of 
total  exports  in  Bulgaria  and  Rumania  and  more  than  one-half  in  Hun- 
gary. The  evidence  suggests  that  in  the  postwar  years  investment  in  agri- 
culture in  these  countries  was  neglected  in  favor  of  highly  publicized 
industrialization  plans,  with  a  consequent  falling  off  of  food  production 
and  exports.  This  tendency  was  de-emphasized  after  Stalin's  death  with 
results  that  are  not  yet  ascertainable.  Extensive  land  reform  schemes  in 
Eastern  Europe  have  broken  up  the  large  estates  and  a  relentless  struggle 
against  the  more  prosperous  peasants  (kulaks)  and  also  those  peasants 
suspected  of  anti-Communist  sentiments  is  still  in  progress.  In  spite  of 
widespread,  mostly  passive,  resistance  by  the  peasants,  the  Communist 
regimes  are  pressing  their  programs  of  collectivization.  Throughout  the 
satellite  countries,  the  peasant  is  subject  to  rigid  state  controls  in  regard 
to  production  and  marketing. 

In  other  sectors  of  the  economies  of  Eastern  Europe,  according  to  offi- 
cial claims,  socialization  has  been  carried  to  the  extent  that  between  70 
and  95  per  cent  of  the  value  of  output  is  being  produced  in  the  socialized 
sectors. 

Estimates  of  the  trade  of  Eastern  Europe  with  the  U.S.S.R.  and  data  on 
trade  with  the  Free  World  were  given  above.  As  was  indicated,  little  is 
known  about  the  precise  composition  of  this  trade.  East  Germany  and 

43  United  Nations,  Statistical  Year  Book,  1953,  p.  111. 


494       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

Czechoslovakia,  and  to  a  lesser  extent,  Poland  and  Hungary  supply  metals, 
engineering  products,  and  chemicals  both  to  the  U.S.S.R.  and  the  other 
satellites.  East  Germany  is  an  important  source  of  uranium  for  the  Soviet 
atomic  energy  program,  as  well  as  a  supplier  of  electrical  equipment  and 
precision  mechanical  and  optical  products.  Poland  supplies  coal  and  Hun- 
gary bauxite.  The  U.S.S.R.  supplies  raw  materials  and  foodstuffs  to  Czech- 
oslovakia and  East  Germany.44 

It  is  reasonably  clear  that  the  volume  of  this  trade  ( which  until  recently 
included  some  reparations  deliveries  from  East  Germany,  Hungary,  and 
Rumania )  is  fairly  substantial  and  that  its  composition  and  terms  are  con- 
trolled by  the  U.S.S.R.  in  its  favor.  What  is  not  completely  clear  is  the  ex- 
tent to  which  the  integration  of  the  Eastern  European  countries  with  the 
U.S.S.R.  enters  into  the  economic  planning  of  these  countries  and  of  intra- 
bloc  trade.  Official  Soviet  and  satellite  spokesmen  have  repeatedly  declared 
that  economic  integration  of  the  satellites  is  the  aim  of  Soviet  policy,  and 
that  investment  and  trade  plans  will  emphasize  the  comparative  advan- 
tages of  the  satellites  to  bring  about  an  intra-bloc  specialization  and  divi- 
sion of  labor.  According  to  Oleg  Hoeffding, 

A  writer  in  Bol'shevik,  for  instance,  has  denied  any  intention  of  turning  the 
satellite  states  "separately  into  self-sufficient  units,"  and  affirmed  division  of 
labor  among  them  as  the  objective.  Each  member  must  industrialize,  with  em- 
phasis on  heavy  industry,  but  "there  is  no  need  for  them  to  create  simultaneously 
all  branches  of  heavy  industry,  which  in  any  event  would  be  too  heavy  a  task 
for  most  of  these  countries."  Each  country  should  develop  "those  heavy  indus- 
tries whose  expansion  is  favored  by  local  conditions  (such  as_  an  adequate  raw 
materials  base ) ,  and  those  whose  products  are  relatively  scarce  in  the  socialist 
camp  as  a  whole.  Of  course,  the  range  of  such  industries  will  be  wider  in  the 
industrially  stronger  countries,  e.g.,  Czechoslovakia,  Poland  and  Hungary,  than 
in  Rumania,  Bulgaria  or  Albania." 


45 


Such  a  policy  of  integration  may  well  be  in  conflict  with  overriding 
geopolitical  and  strategic  considerations,  according  to  which  the  U.S.S.R. 
may  wish  to  keep  these  states  viable,  to  levy  on  them  for  military  pur- 
poses, and  to  keep  the  populations  in  a  state  of  relative  docility,  all  in 
order  to  enhance  their  ability  to  provide  a  defensive  buffer  against  pos- 
sible attack  from  Western  Europe,  or  alternatively  a  staging  area  for  a 
Soviet  drive  in  the  other  direction.  Nevertheless  there  is  developing  a 
fairly  extensive  economic  interdependence  between  Eastern  Europe  and 
the  U.S.S.R. 

44  O.  Hoeffding,  "Soviet  Economic  Relations  with  the  Orbit"  in  Bergson,  op.  cit., 
pp.  331-334. 

45  Ibid.,  p.  327,  the  inner  quotations  are  from  an  article  by  I.  Dudinski  in  Bol'shevik, 
No.  19  (1950),  p.  33. 


GROWING  ECONOMIC  STRENGTH  OF  SINO-SOVIET  BLOC    495 

C.    Communist  China 

INTRODUCTION 

The  rise  of  Communism  to  power  in  China  at  the  mid-point  of  the 
twentieth  century  poses  some  interesting  problems  for  the  student  of 
political  geography.  What  has  the  Communization  of  China  done— what 
will  it  do— to  the  geographical  distribution  of  power,  not  only  as  between 
"East"  and  "West"  but  also  within  the  Soviet  Bloc? 

China  is  a  country  of  about  3.5  million  square  miles  and  roughly  600 
million  people  46  compared  to  9.1  million  square  miles  and  300  million 
people  in  the  European  Soviet  Bloc. 

Is  this  vast  area  with  its  teeming  population  as  significant  an  addition 
to  the  mass  and  might  of  Soviet  power  as  a  comparison  merely  of  size  and 
numbers  would  indicate?  In  modern  times  China  had  never  been  an  effec- 
tively unified  national  state.  Its  industrial  and  military  power  remained 
slight,  and  throughout  the  nineteenth  and  the  first  half  of  the  twentieth 
centuries  China  was  a  pawn  of  the  Western  imperial  powers  and  of  Japan. 
Can  such  a  community  contribute  very  greatly  to  the  power  of  the  Soviet 
bloc?  And  if,  as  recent  evidence  suggests,  China  under  the  ruthless  disci- 
pline of  Communism  will  eventually  develop  industrial  and  military  re- 
sources to  match  its  size  and  population,  will  these  new  capabilities  be 
placed  wholly  at  the  service  of  the  center  of  Communist  power  in  Mos- 
cow? Or  will  Communism  in  China  be  subjected  to  the  immemorial  expe- 
rience of  other  invasions— military,  political  and  cultural— and  produce  a 
Sinicized  Communism  rather  than  a  Sovietized  China?  In  this  chapter 
we  will  confine  ourselves  to  the  first  question:  what  economic  capabilities, 
present  and  potential,  can  China  contribute  to  the  power  of  Soviet  Com- 
munism? In  thus  limiting  our  appraisal,  however,  we  do  not  assume  that 
these  tangible  capabilities  are  more  significant  than  are  the  intangible 
elements  affecting  China's  power  position. 

GENERAL  FEATURES  OF  THE  CHINESE  ECONOMY 

The  China  taken  over  by  the  Communists  was  a  dual  economy:  one 
small  part  urban-industrial,  the  other  and  far  larger  part  rural,  peasant, 
agricultural.  In  the  modern  part  of  the  economy  were  large  coastal  cities 

46  Actually  582.6  million  for  mainland  China  as  of  June  30,  1953,  according  to 
Peiping's  National  Bureau  of  Statistics  (New  York  Times,  November  2,  1954).  Prior 
to  this  the  generally  accepted  figure  was  around  475  million.  See  Chapter  9,  pp.  300- 
301,  325. 


496       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

like  Shanghai,  Canton,  and  Tientsin,  but  four-fifths  of  the  population 
lived  as  peasants  on  small,  three  or  four  acre  farms  and  agricultural  pro- 
duction constituted  70  per  cent  of  China's  national  income.  Population 
density  was  greater  than  in  any  other  part  of  mainland  Asia  except  India, 
because  of  the  favorable  effect  of  the  monsoon  rains  on  the  growth  of 
vegetable  crops  in  the  eastern  plain  where  most  of  the  population  is 
concentrated. 


PRINCIPAL  GEOGRAPHICAL  REGIONS  47 

Economic  activity  in  China  shows  the  effect  of  climate  and  other  physi- 
cal features  of  the  geography.  Most  of  China  is  north  of  the  Tropical 
Zone,  extending  from  about  18°  to  53°  North,  and  most  of  it  is  moun- 
tainous. However,  China  has  an  extensive  sea  coast,  with  many  excellent 
harbors,  adjacent  to  which  are  the  great  alluvial  plains  drained  by  the 
Hwang  Ho  (Yellow)  and  Yangtse  rivers.  These  plains  extend  from  north 
of  Peiping  to  south  of  the  Yangtse. 

South  of  the  Great  Wall  "China  proper"  is  divided  into  three  fairly 
distinct  geographical  regions,  South,  Central,  and  North  China.  South 
China  is  a  mountainous  region  with  forests  producing  lumber,  tung  oil, 
camphor,  wax,  and  bamboo.  The  warm  rainy  summers  are  favorable  to 
a  number  of  sub-tropical  crops,  such  as  rice,  sugar  cane,  and  cotton,  which 
are  cultivated  in  the  alluvial  valleys.  Tea  is  grown  on  the  mountain  sides, 
especially  in  Fukien  Province.  Many  of  the  people  of  the  maritime  re- 
gions are  fishermen  or  coastal  traders;  some  are  pirates.  To  the  west  the 
land  rises  to  the  mountains  of  Tibet  through  limestone  hills  containing 
tin  and  other  minerals.  The  principal  river  of  this  region  is  the  Si-kiang, 
which  rises  in  the  plateau  of  Yunnan  and,  crossing  Kwangsi  Province, 
creates  a  great  delta  at  the  head  of  which  lies  Canton,  a  major  port  city 
where  silk,  woolen,  and  cotton  goods  are  manufactured.  It  is  from  this 
area  of  China  that  most  overseas  Chinese  have  migrated,  because  here 
the  environment  was  most  favorable  to  population  growth. 

Central  China  is  dominated  by  the  Yangtse  River,  the  longest  of  China's 
great  rivers.  In  the  Yangtse  valley  the  summer  rains  last  longer  and  there 
is  a  second  period  of  rainfall  in  September  and  October.  The  winters, 
while  cold,  are  neither  so  harsh  nor  so  dry  as  those  of  North  China.  This 

47  For  a  detailed  description  see  G.  B.  Cressey,  Asia's  Land  and  Peoples,  2nd  ed. 
(New  York,  1951),  pp.  34-165,  and  the  comprehensive  bibliography  on  pp.  551-557; 
also  W.  G.  East  and  O.  H.  K.  Spate,  The  Changing  Map  of  Asia  (London,  1950), 
pp.  249-277;  for  an  excellent  brief  summary  of  China's  "geographical  setting"  see 
K.  S.  Latourette,  A  History  of  Modern  China  (London,  1954),  pp.  17-23. 


GROWING  ECONOMIC  STRENGTH  OF  SINO-SOVIET  BLOC    497 

valley  of  about  700,000  square  miles  contains  more  than  one-third  of  the 
population  of  China.  In  its  upper  regions,  the  Red  Basin,  above  the  Ichang 
Gorge,  the  crops  include  wheat,  rice,  millet,  sugar,  tobacco,  and  tea.  In 
the  central  basins  and  delta  of  the  Yangtse  the  land  is  intensively  culti- 
vated to  produce  wheat,  rice,  cotton,  tea,  and  silk.  Here  also  are  some  im- 
portant manufacturing  cities  (Fig.  15-3):  Hankow  (cotton,  hemp,  and 
flour  mills),  Hanyang  (iron  and  steel),  Nanking  (cotton,  silk,  and  paper 
mills),  and  Shanghai,  the  chief  entrepot  for  central  China,  one  of  the 
largest  Chinese  cities,  and,  formerly  at  least,  the  financial  center  of  all 
China.  The  Yangtse  is  navigable  to  Hankow  for  ocean-going  ships. 

The  third  principal  region  of  "China  proper"  comprises  the  great  plains 
of  North  China  and  the  loess  plateau  of  the  northwest.  This  part  of  China 
is  covered  with  the  famous  yellow  soil  known  as  loess,  borne  from  inner 
Asia  on  the  dry  northwest  winter  winds.  The  summers  are  warm,  with  not 
so  much  rain  as  farther  south,  and  the  winters  are  very  cold.  Though 
extremely  fertile,  loess  is  porous  and  does  not  retain  moisture  long.  The 
crops  in  this  region  are  therefore  unusually  susceptible  to  damage  by 
drought.  The  staple  crops  are  wheat,  peas,  beans,  and  millet.  This  area  is 
drained  by  the  Hwang  Ho,  called  "China's  Sorrow"  because  of  its  disas- 
trous flooding.  The  Shantung  Peninsula,  a  hilly  region  lying  between  the 
old  and  new  (1852)  beds  of  the  Hwang  Ho  is  the  most  important  silk- 
producing  region  in  China.  The  Hwang  Ho  is  not  navigable  by  vessels  of 
any  size. 

The  barriers  between  these  three  districts  have  not  been  so  great  as  to 
preclude  cultural  and  political  unity.48  Great  as  are  the  distances  between 
the  farthest  margins,  "the  space  relations  of  Peiping,  Nanking  and  Canton 
at  least  in  terms  of  air  travel  are  comparable  with  those  of  Stockholm, 
Prague  and  Rome,  those  of  Nanking  and  Chunking  with  London  and 
Prague."  49 

It  is  in  the  eighteen  provinces  of  "China  proper,"  50  with  the  three  main 
divisions  just  described,  that  the  human  life,  culture,  and  economic  ac- 
tivity of  traditional  China  were  concentrated.  These  eighteen  provinces 
contain  almost  all  of  the  agricultural  land  of  China  except  that  in  the 
northeastern  provinces  (Manchuria).  One  authority51  has  preferred  to 
combine  "China  proper"  with  the  soy  bean-kaoliang  area  of  Manchuria 
and  to  speak  of  agricultural  China  in  contrast  to  outer  China  to  the  west. 

48  Latourette,  op.  cit.,  p.  18. 

49  East  and  Spate,  op.  cit.,  p.  250. 

50  Ibid.,  p.  262,  for  a  map  showing  the  eighteen  provinces  of  "China  proper"  in 
relation  to  the  outlying  provinces. 

51  Cressey,  op.  cit.,  p.  100. 


o 

o 

c 

o 


E 

3 

"3 

1- 

4-1 

ft 


0 

a 

cj 

■a 

_* 

eg 

0 

u 

(N 

0 

4- 

•  r\ 

CJ 

S 

a 

1) 

4— 

la 

in 

S 

B 

n 

s 

o 

B 

— 

Si 

T, 

3 

B 

~a 

3 

c 

-c 

^^ ^ 

C 

i— i 

a 

— 

T3 

V 

es 

u 

S 

a; 

X 

0 

CJ 

— 

ft 

s 

„ 

hi 

cr 

4i  T3 

JS 

CS 

s- 
0 

0 
— 

* 

C3 

u 

— 

c 

< — - 

c£ 

B 

0 

rx 

ej 

T) 

M 

a 

0 
- 

y 

B 
c 

es 

u 

— . 

10 

M 

— 

*-* 

■s. 

9 

1= 

B 

M 

-s 

B 

A 

^ 

Cfl 

U 

U 

i- 

3 

a 

s 

it 

« 

on 

-c 

M 

0 

In 

c; 

sc 

W 

10 

M 

0 

M 

U- 

498 


GROWING  ECONOMIC  STRENGTH  OF  SINO-SOVIET  BLOC    499 

Agricultural  China  is  subdivided  in  turn  into  nine  agricultural  regions, 
four  in  the  wheat,  millet,  and  kaoliang  areas  of  the  north  and  five  in  the 
rice-producing  regions  of  the  south.52  These  areas  include  about  1,660,000 
square  miles,  or  less  than  half  of  greater  China  which  also  includes  Inner 
Mongolia,  Sinkiang,  and  Tibet. 

The  Chinese  Empire  in  the  nineteenth  century  possessed  a  number  of 
outlying  dependencies,  including  Manchuria,  Mongolia,  Sinkiang  (Chi- 
nese Turkestan),  and  Tibet.  So  many  Chinese  migrated  to  Manchuria  in 
the  early  part  of  this  century  that  it  is  now  overwhelmingly  Chinese  and  is 
referred  to  as  the  Northeastern  Provinces.  Manchuria  is  industrially  the 
most  important  region  of  present-day  China,  due  to  the  Japanese  who  built 
railways  and  developed  mines  and  factories  there,  finally  seizing  the  coun- 
try in  1932  and  setting  up  a  puppet  state.  Outer  Mongolia,  north  of  the 
Gobi,  and  the  historic  seat  of  the  Mongols,  broke  away  from  China  under 
the  Republic  and  became  the  Peoples  Republic  of  Outer  Mongolia  under 
Soviet  domination.  The  Communists  have  once  more  established  Chinese 
sovereignty  over  Tibet  and  Sinkiang.  These  enormous  territories  are 
sparsely  populated  and  at  present  of  little  or  no  importance  economically. 
However,  they  loom  large  as  strategic  areas,  to  be  developed  by  new  rail- 
ways, highways,  and  air  routes,  between  Soviet  Central  Asia  and  Commu- 
nist China. 

NATURAL  RESOURCES 

Since  China  is  still  primarily  agricultural,  its  most  important  resource 
is  its  arable  land.  Over  half  of  the  area  of  China  consists  of  waste  ( large 
areas  are  seriously  eroded)  or  is  built  upon;  20  per  cent  is  pastoral  country 
(mostly  in  Mongolia,  Sinkiang,  and  Tibet)  and  the  remainder  is  about 
equally  divided  between  woodland  and  arable  land.  In  absolute  figures, 
there  are  about  750,000  square  miles  of  pastoral  land,  325,000  square  miles 
of  woodland  and  350,000  square  miles  of  arable  land.  With  a  population 
of  582.6  million,  there  is  thus  about  0.38  of  an  acre  of  arable  land  per 
capita.53  An  earlier  estimate  puts  the  total  cultivated  land  at  362,082 
square  miles,  or  27  per  cent  for  the  twenty-two  provinces  and  425,000 
square  miles,  or  nearly  12  per  cent,  for  all  of  greater  China.54  This  esti- 
mate would  give  0.45  acres  per  capita  which  by  coincidence  is  the  same  as 
much  earlier  official  estimates.  The  twenty-two  provinces  are  the  eighteen 

52lhid.,-p.  96. 

53  Stamp  and  Gilmour,  op.  cit.,  p.  613,  based  on  Food  and  Agriculture  Organization 
( FAO )  reports  covering  22  provinces. 

54  Cressey,  op.  cit.,  pp.  89,  90,  based  on  J.  L.  Buck,  Land  Utilization  in  China 
(Chicago,  1937). 


500       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

provinces  of  "China  proper"  referred  to  above,  plus  the  two  provinces, 
Chahar  and  Jehol,  of  inner  Mongolia  and  the  two  provinces,  Tsinghai  and 
Sikang,  of  eastern  Tibet.  These  twenty-two  provinces,  though  excluding 
the  northeastern  provinces  ( Manchuria ) ,  contain  nearly  2  million  square 
miles  and  over  80  per  cent  of  the  arable  land.  More  than  90  per  cent  of  the 
people  of  China  live  in  these  provinces. 

While  the  soil,  whether  of  the  alluvial  river  valleys  of  central  and  south 
China,  or  of  the  loess  plateaus  of  the  north,  is  fertile  and  moreover  is  in- 
tensively cultivated,  population  pressure  is  probably  high.  Over-all  popu- 
lation density  for  Greater  China  is  about  167  persons  per  square  mile  based 
on  3.5  million  square  miles  and  close  to  600  million  people.  This  is  a 
moderate  density  when  compared  with  Japan  (601),  Belgium  (740),  or 
the  Netherlands  (830).55  For  "China  proper"  or  "agricultural  China," 
however,  the  population  density  would  be  in  the  neighborhood  of  275  to 
315  per  square  mile.  In  terms  of  cultivated  land,  however,  the  average 
density  of  population  would  be  more  like  1,400  persons  per  square  mile, 
and  in  places  there  are  over  2,000. 56 

China  is  between  the  first  and  second  stages  of  demographic  develop- 
ment, with  very  high  birth,  death,  and  infant  mortality  rates.  In  the  past, 
high  death  and  infant  mortality  rates  together  with  some  emigration  have 
kept  the  rate  of  population  increase  low,  but  Communist  planning  will 
probably  have  to  deal  with  a  formidable  rate  of  increase  as  public-health 
and  related  measures  reduce  the  death  and  infant  mortality  rates. 

China  probably  has  very  considerable  mineral  resources  (cf.  Fig.  15-3, 
p.  498),  but  they  have  been  neither  carefully  explored  nor  effectively 
exploited.  There  is  much  excellent  coal,  both  anthracite  and  bituminous, 
especially  in  the  north  China  province  of  Shansi.  Shansi  also  has  very  good 
iron  ores  and  there  are  other  deposits  in  Hupeh  and  Seechwan,  but  the 
largest  iron  ore  deposits  are  in  Manchuria  and  it  is  here  that  China's  iron 
and  steel  industry  is  being  developed.  On  the  basis  of  iron  content  of  ore 
reserves  per  capita,  however,  China's  known  reserves  are  extremely  small 
in  relation  to  other  countries.  Yunnan  has  rich  copper  deposits,  and 
Hunan  Province  contains  the  world's  chief  deposit  of  antimony.  Chinese 
tungsten  production  in  1950  was  11,000  tons,  more  than  one-third  of  total 
world  output.  In  the  same  year  tin  smelter  output  was  only  4,000  tons  out 
of  a  world  total  of  175,000  tons.  Although  little  or  no  aluminum  is  pro- 
duced, there  are  ample  deposits  ( 200  million  tons )  of  high-grade  bauxite. 

55  1952  estimates  from  United  Nations  Statistical  Yearbook,  1953,  pp.  27-30,  con- 
verted from  square  kilometers. 

56  Cressey,  op.  cit.,  p.  86. 


GROWING  ECONOMIC  STRENGTH  OF  SINO-SOVIET  BLOC     501 

On  the  negative  side,  China's  most  serious  deficiency  is  in  oil,  a  situation 
which  it  shares  with  India.57 

The  mineral  position  has  been  summed  up  as  follows: 

China  is  bountifully  supplied  with  coal  and  has  major  reserves  of  antimony 
and  tungsten.  Tin  and  iron  are  available  in  moderate  amounts,  and  there  are 
small  quantities  of  a  wide  variety  of  minerals.  Copper,  sulphur,  petroleum,  and 
other  essentials  appear  very  limited.  China  has  the  mineral  basis  for  a  modest 
industrialization,  but  in  terms  of  her  population  she  ranks  well  down  the  list  of 
the  great  powers.  Nevertheless,  no  other  area  on  the  Pacific  side  of  Asia  is  better 
supplied. 

.  .  .  Few  areas  in  the  world  present  the  basic  industrial  opportunities  that 
China  will  seek  to  develop  during  the  remainder  of  the  twentieth  century.  Many 
of  these  problems  rest  on  heavy  industry  and  in  turn  upon  geology.  The  situation 
is  somewhat  comparable  to  the  problems  of  the  Soviet  Five-Year  Plans,  but 
unlike  the  U.S.S.R.,  China  is  only  modestly  endowed  with  natural  wealth.  It  is 
fortunate  that  coal  is  super-abundant  for  it  is  the  key  to  power  and  to  chemical 
industry,  but  the  shortage  in  iron  will  be  serious  before  many  decades. 


58 


Per  capita  consumption  of  energy  in  China  was  less  than  200  pounds, 
coal  equivalent,  in  1937,  putting  China  among  the  very  low  energy-con- 
suming countries,  along  with  India,  Burma,  Haiti,  and  the  Belgian  Congo. 
Almost  three-quarters  of  the  total  energy  was  used  for  heat  and  light, 
18  per  cent  for  industry  and  only  10  per  cent  for  transport.  About  57  per 
cent  of  China's  energy  comes  from  coal,  35  per  cent  from  wood  and  peat, 
only  4  per  cent  from  water  power,  and  only  3  per  cent  from  oil  and  gas. 
Northwest  China  is  believed  to  contain  some  promising  oil-bearing  struc- 
tures but  crude  oil  production  in  China  has  been  negligible.  China  is 
estimated  to  have  about  22  million  horse  power  of  potential  water  power 
available  95  per  cent  of  the  time,  and  41  million  available  50  per  cent  of 
the  time  ( due  to  uneven  stream  flow ) ,  but  practically  none  of  it  is  devel- 
oped. This  is  less  than  India,  Pakistan,  and  Ceylon  together  (40  million) 
but  more  than  Japan  ( 16  million )  .£ 


59 


TRANSPORTATION 

Before  the  development  of  rail  and  highway  transport,  the  rivers  and 
the  sea  coast  were  China's  principal  arteries  for  travel.  The  principal 
rivers,  running  west  to  east,  were  navigable  at  least  by  small  craft  for 
considerable  distances  inland,  especially  the  Yangtse,  which  is  navigable 

57  The  two  countries  have  also  in  common  that  they  both  possess  large  resources  of 
coal.  India,  however,  has  the  advantage  that  its  coal  is  in  general  of  better  quality, 
is  more  easily  accessible,  and,  most  important,  lies  near  its  iron  ore  resources. 

58  Cressey,  op.  cit.,  pp.  79,  85. 

59  Woytinsky,  op.  cit.,  pp.  887,  935,  942-3;  also  Cressey,  op.  cit.,  pp.  80,  81. 


502        THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

by  river  steamer  as  far  as  Chungking.  In  the  mountainous  south,  human 
porterage  was  the  chief  other  means  of  transport.  In  the  north,  mules  and 
horses  were  used  to  pull  wagons,  and  together  with  asses  and  camels,  for 
beasts  of  burden.  To  a  large  extent  these  methods  are  still  employed. 

The  railways  of  China  were  developed  slowly,  by  foreign  capital,  ex- 
tending inland  from  the  treaty  ports.  In  this  way  Canton  was  connected 
with  Hong  Kong;  Nanking,  Hangchow,  and  Ningpo  with  Shanghai;  and 
Kunming  (by  the  French)  with  Haiphong  in  Indo-China.  The  most  ex- 
tensive development  was  in  the  north  where  Peiping  and  Tientsin  were 
linked  to  Manchuria  and  Inner  Mongolia.  By  1936  the  Canton-Hankow 
railroad  was  completed  linking  the  north  and  south  positions  of  the 
system60  (cf.  Fig.  15-3,  p.  498). 

At  the  end  of  World  War  II  mainland  China  had  almost  17,000  miles  of 
railway  of  which  about  14,000  miles  were  serviceable.  There  was  extensive 
destruction  during  the  civil  war  but  by  1951  reconstruction  had  brought 
the  total  of  serviceable  mileage  up  to  about  13,500  miles.61  Most  of  this 
mileage  is  single-tracked.  Double-tracked  lines  run  from  Harbin  to  Muk- 
den, from  Mukden  to  Dairen  and  Tientsin,  from  Tientsin  to  Peiping,  and 
from  Siichow  to  Nanking.  The  highest  recorded  annual  volume  of  rail 
freight  transported  by  China's  railways  was  6.5  billion  ton  kilometers  in 
1937.  In  1947  the  figure  was  5.3  billion  ton  kilometers.62  Considering  the 
area  and  population  of  China  this  constitutes  a  very  low  utilization  of 
railway  service. 

In  1937  there  were  only  some  15,000  miles  of  paved  roads  and  35,000 
miles  of  dry- weather  earth  roads. 

Under  the  Communists  attention  seems  to  have  been  concentrated  on 
rebuilding  the  railroads  and  reorganizing  them  in  the  interest  of  greater 
efficiency,  rather  than  on  new  construction.  All  railroads  are  now  under 
a  single  administration,  and  the  control  of  the  Harbin-Dairen  line  in 
Manchuria  was  reportedly  restored  by  the  U.S.S.R.  to  China  in  1953. 63 
While  the  conspicuous  deficiency  that  appears  on  any  map  of  the  Chinese 
railway  system  is  the  lack  of  feeder  lines,  the  government  seems  bent  in- 
stead on  using  surfaced  highways.  This  plan,  plus  the  difficulty  and  cost 
of  rail  construction  in  the  rugged  terrain  of  the  south,  and  the  growing 
potential  of  air  transport,  suggest  that,  except  for  railways  constructed 
into  the  outlying  dependencies  for  strategic  purposes  or  to  exploit  new 

60  East  and  Spate,  op.  cit.,  p.  261. 

61  N.  Ginsburg,  "China's  Railroad  Network."  Geographical  Review  (July,  1951). 
p.  470. 

62  United  Nations,  Statistical  Yearbook,  1953,  p.  297. 

63  New  York  Times,  January  1,  1953,  p.  3. 


GROWING  ECONOMIC  STRENGTH  OF  SINO-SOVIET  BLOC    503 

resources,  the  Chinese  will  not  embark  on  an  overambitious  railway  ex- 
pansion.64 

New  rail  construction  that  is  under  way  or  may  have  been  completed 
by  the  Communists  include  the  line  from  Liuchow  in  the  south  to  the 
Indo-China  border  at  Chinnankuan,  the  line  from  Chungking  to  Chengtu 
projected  by  the  Nationalists,  and  the  extension  of  the  Lungsi  railway  to 
Lanchow  in  Kansu.65 

Plans  for  eventual  integration  of  the  Soviet  and  Chinese  transportation 
systems  (cf.  Fig.  15-3,  p.  498)  call  for  the  construction  of  railways  west 
through  the  Kansu  corridor  from  Lanchow  through  Sinkiang  via  Hami  and 
Urumchi  to  Alma-Ata  on  the  Soviet  border;  and  north  from  Tsinin  through 
Ulan  Bator  in  Outer  Mongolia  to  the  Trans-Siberian  at  Ulan  Ude.  On  both 
rail  lines,  considerable  progress  has  been  reported.66  The  eventual  eco- 
nomic importance  of  the  two  rail  lines,  to  both  China  and  the  Soviet 
Union,  will  be  considerable.  The  Tsinin-Ulan  Bator  railway  will  shorten 
the  journey  from  Pekin  to  Ulan  Ude  by  more  than  650  miles.  The  Lan- 
chow-Alma-Ata  line  will  open  up  access  to  the  untapped  mineral  resources 
of  China's  North-West.  It  will  also  facilitate  the  movement  of  settlers  from 
the  over-populated  eastern  provinces  to  Sinkiang  and  thus  promote  the  de- 
velopment of  the  oil,  coal,  lead,  zinc  resources  of  that  province.  The  future 
economic  importance  of  the  two  railroads,  however,  is  overshadowed  by 
their  immediate  strategic  value.67 

AGRICULTURE 

The  principal  crops  are  wheat  and  rice,  but  barley,  corn,  millet,  sor- 
ghum, and  sweet  potatoes  are  grown  in  large  quantities.  China  also  pro- 
duces, in  Manchuria,  almost  one-half  the  world  supply  of  soybeans.  The 
statistics  on  crop  production  in  China  given  by  FAO  are  for  the  twenty- 
two  provinces. 

That  China  accounts  for  a  substantial  proportion  of  the  world  supply 
of  many  of  the  above  crops  is  only  a  reflection  of  the  fact  that  China  con- 
tains a  large  proportion  of  the  world's  population  and  that  most  of  these 
people  subsist  by  agriculture.  Actually,  their  agriculture,  while  intensive, 
and  employing  in  many  cases  ancient  but  effective  methods  of  irrigation 

64  Ginsburg,  op.  cit.,  p.  474. 

65  Ibid.,  p.  473. 

66  See  p.  498. 

67  A.  White,  Recent  Railroad  Expansion  in  Soviet  Asia,  unpublished  (Washington, 
1953);  see  also  Ginsburg,  op.  cit.,  p.  473,  and  East  and  Spate,  op.  cit.,  pp.  357,  358, 
585. 


504       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

( about  half  the  land  is  irrigated,  and  about  a  fourth  is  terraced,  mainly  for 
rice),  is  inefficient  in  terms  of  labor  inputs.  The  average  farm  is  small, 
only  about  four  acres,  and  may  consist  of  six  or  seven  parcels.  The  average 
farm  family  size  is  approximately  six  persons.68  Except  for  rice,  sorghum, 
and  millet  yields  per  acre  are  not  exceptional.  There  is  very  little  mecha- 
nized equipment  in  use;  in  1949  there  were  only  1,400  farm  tractors  in  the 
22  provinces.  Wooden  spades  and  hoes  are  common.  Grain  is  often 
threshed  on  a  stone,  wheat  is  harvested  with  a  sickle,  and  the  plow  is 
pulled  by  an  ox  or  a  water  buffalo  if  the  farmer  is  well-off,  otherwise  by 
members  of  the  family.  Hired  labor  accounts  for  only  about  one-fifth  of 
the  total  labor  performed.69 

TABLE  15-8 
Production  and  Yields  of  Principal  Crops,  China's  22  Provinces,  1949  * 


YIELD  PER 

AVERAGE  WORLD 

MILLION 

ACRE  METRIC 

PER  CENT  OF 

YIELD  METRIC 

CROP 

TONS 

ACRES 

QUINTALS 

WORLD  SUPPLY 

QUINTALS 

Wheat 

20.6 

52.6 

3.9 

12.2 

3.9 

Rice 

44.5 

45.7 

9.7 

29.4 a 

6.6" 

Barley 

6.6 

15.3 

4.3 

13.5 

4.4 

Corn 

6.5 

12.3 

5.3 

4.6 

6.5 

Millet 

7.1 

16.2 

4.3 

39.7 a 

2.6b 

Sorghum 

5.4 

10.8 

5.1 

32.1 a 

3.0b 

Rape  Seed 

3.1 

14.0 

Soybeans 

4.9 

n.a. 

n.a. 

34.7 

n.a. 

Cotton 

0.4 

5.3 

0.8 c 

7.6 

1.0C 

Tea 

12.7d 

n.a. 

n.a. 

2.6 

n.a. 

Tobacco 

0.5 

1.2 

4.5 

13.5 

4.2 

a  Excluding  U.S.S.R. 
b  Excludes  U.S.S.R. 
c  Tons  per  acre. 
d  1948  in  thousands  of  tons. 

*  W.  S.  and  E.  S.  Woytinsky,  World  Population  and  Production  (New  York,  1954),  based  on   Yearbook 
of  Food  and  Agriculture  Statistics. 


The  laborious  character  of  Chinese  agriculture  is  indicated  by  calcula- 
tions showing  that  one  acre  of  wheat  requires  26  man-days  of  labor  com- 
pared with  1.2  man-days  in  the  United  States;  one  acre  of  corn  requires 
23  days  in  China,  but  2.5  days  in  the  United  States;  one  acre  of  cotton  53 
days,  but  only  14  in  the  United  States.70 

Animal  husbandry  is  unimportant  save  in  the  northwest.  "It  is  a  ques- 
tion, not  of  climate  or  soil,  but  of  resources  and  population.  The  relation 

68  Cressey,  op.  cit.,  p.  90. 

69  R.  H.  Tawney,  Land  and  Labour  in  China  (London,  1937).  p.  33.  This  is  an  ex- 
cellent and  vivid  portrayal  of  the  rural  economy  of  China. 

'!0  Cressey,  op.  cit.,  p.  89. 


GROWING  ECONOMIC  STRENGTH  OF  SINO-SOVIET  BLOC    505 

between  them  has  for  many  centuries  been  such  that  land  capable  of 
growing  food  for  human  consumption  cannot  be  spared  for  raising  beasts. 
Milk  and  meat  will  support  fewer  human  beings  than  can  be  fed  from  the 
land  which,  if  cattle  were  reared,  would  be  required  to  grow  fodder."  71 
Such  grass  as  does  grow  in  the  hill  near  the  villages  is  needed  for  fuel. 
Only  ducks,  chickens,  and  pigs  are  kept  by  China's  peasant  and  these  sub- 
sist on  waste  products  from  the  farm.  Thus  there  is  little  animal  manure, 
and  commercial  fertilizers  are  practically  unknown. 

These  conditions,  the  small  size  of  most  farms,  and  the  absence  of  any 
but  primitive  tools,  determine  the  character  and  efficiency  of  Chinese 
agriculture.  "The  prevalence  of  minute  holdings  has  necessitated  special 
methods  of  cultivation  in  order  to  make  them  yield  a  livelihood;  and  these 
methods  in  turn,  involving  as  they  do,  much  detailed  vigilance  and  heavy 
physical  labor,  are  of  a  kind  which  can  be  applied  only  when  holdings 
are  minute  .  . .  the  Chinese  farmer  .  .  .  has  acquired  an  ingenuity  which  has 
rarely  been  surpassed  in  wringing  from  the  land  at  his  disposal,  not  indeed 
the  most  that  it  could  yield— for  the  output  could  be  increased  by  the  use 
of  modern  methods— but  the  utmost  possible  with  the  resources  that  he 
has  hitherto  commanded.  ...  It  is  the  agriculture  of  a  pre-scientific  age, 
raised  by  centuries  of  venerable  tradition  to  the  dignity  of  an  art .  .  . 
a  triumph  of  individual  skill  unaided  by  organized  knowledge.  .  .  .  But 
( its )  economic  significance  has  not  always  been  appreciated,  and  admirers 
of  the  technical  expertness  of  the  Chinese  farmer  seem  sometimes  to  for- 
get the  human  cost  at  which  his  triumphs  are  won."  72 

And  the  social  cost:  "The  Chinese  farmer  grows  only  enough  food  for 
himself  and  one  other  person  outside  his  family.  There  is  thus  no  agricul- 
tural surplus  to  feed  an  expanding  urban  population."  73  What  is  provided 
is  not  excessive.  There  are  no  aggregate  data,  but  per  capita  food  con- 
sumption is  not  likely  to  be  much  higher  than  FAO's  estimate  of  2,700 
calories  per  person  for  all  of  East  Asia. 

INDUSTRY  AND  TRADE 

The  modern,  urban-industrial  sector  of  the  Chinese  economy,  referred 
to  above,  developed  only  in  a  few  coastal  cities  where  western  concessions 
and  settlements  were  established,  and  in  Japanese-controlled  Manchuria 
( cf.  Fig.  15-3,  p.  498 ) .  In  China  proper  the  cotton  textile  industry  became 

71  Tawney,  op.  cit.,  p.  27. 

72  Tawney,  op.  cit.,  pp.  44-46. 

73  Cressey,  op.  cit. 


506       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

by  far  the  most  important  manufacturing  activity.  In  1949  the  Chinese 
cotton  textile  industry  had  4.6  million  spindles,  the  eighth-largest  cotton 
textile  industry  in  the  world.  About  half  the  spindles  are  located  at 
Shanghai,  the  rest  at  Tientsin,  Tsingtao,  and  Hankow.  About  half  the  mills 
were  owned  by  Japanese  and  passed  into  the  hands  of  the  government 
after  World  War  II.  China  imported  cotton  fiber,  partly  because  the  do- 
mestic cotton  has  a  very  short  staple,  partly  for  re-export  in  the  form  of 
cotton  piece  goods  and  cotton  rugs. 

Other  manufacturing  enterprises,  such  as  flour  milling  and  food  and 
tobacco  processing  were  likewise  concentrated  in  Shanghai,  Tientsin,  and 
Tsingtao.  The  only  heavy  industry  to  speak  of  was  built  up  in  Manchuria 
by  the  Japanese  after  1930.  Mukden  became  a  center  of  armaments  pro- 
duction, an  integrated  iron  and  steel  industry  was  developed  at  Anshan, 
and  similar  expansion  took  place  in  heavy  chemicals,  metal  processing, 
and  railway  equipment  shops.74 

There  are  no  reliable  statistics  of  industrial  production  for  China.  How- 
ever, from  a  speech  made  by  Chou  En-lai  in  October,  1954,  which  com- 
pared output  of  the  leading  industries  for  1954  with  1949,  the  following 
figures  have  been  derived. 

1949  1954 

Electric  Power 

Coal 

Pig  Iron 

Steel  Ingot 

Cement 

Machine  Made  Paper 

Cotton  Yarn 

Metal  Working  Machines 

While  it  is  not  possible  to  verify  the  figures  for  1954,  other  sources  pro- 
vide some  light  on  the  accuracy  of  the  1949  figures  given  by  Chou  En-lai. 
It  should  be  remembered  that  economic  life  in  many  parts  of  China  in 
1949  was  adversely  affected  by  the  final  hostilities  and  dislocation  of  the 
civil  war.  Electric  power  production  in  1950  was  estimated  at  2.2  billion 
kilowatt  hours,  about  two-tenths  of  1  per  cent  of  the  world  total  for  that 
year.  Coal  production  (excluding  Manchuria)  was  16  million  metric  tons 
in  1949  and  37  million  in  1950,  1.1  per  cent  and  2.5  per  cent  of  the  world 
output  excluding  U.S.S.R.  in  those  years.75  Iron  and  steel  production  in 
Manchuria  in  1949  was  94,000  tons  of  pig  iron  and  89,000  tons  of  steel,76 

74  Woytinsky,  op.  cit.,  p.  870. 

75  Ibid.,  p.  870. 
™  Ibid.,  p.  1121. 


billion 

kwh. 

4.30 

10.80 

million 

tons 

31.50 

82.00 

million 

tons 

0.24 

3.03 

million 

tons 

0.16 

2.17 

million 

tons 

0.66, 

4.73 

million 

tons 

0.11 

0.48 

million 

bales 

2.40 

4.60 

units 

13,513 

GROWING  ECONOMIC  STRENGTH  OF  SINO-SOVIET  BLOC     507 

figures  which  still  reflect  the  removal  of  plant  and  equipment  by  the  So- 
viet Union  after  World  War  II.  Whichever  figures  are  correct  they  indi- 
cate beyond  doubt  that  China's  industrial  capabilities  in  1949  were 
insignificant.  Whether  the  impression  of  unusual  growth  which  the  figures 
for  1954  give  can  be  taken  as  a  portent  of  the  future  is  discussed  in  another 
section  below. 

To  the  modern  sector  of  the  Chinese  economy  concentrated  in  the 
coastal  cities,  China's  foreign  trade  was  a  source  of  great  wealth  and 
activity,  although  the  total  volume  of  trade  was  small  in  relation  to 
China's  area  and  population.  Certain  agricultural  products  like  tung  oil 
and  pigs'  bristles  were  exported  in  quantity  but  the  biggest  export  item 
was  cotton  piece  goods.  Principal  imports  were  raw  cotton,  electrical 
equipment  and  other  machinery,  iron  and  steel,  chemicals  and  pharma- 
ceuticals, and  transport  equipment.  A  large  visible  trade  deficit  (import 
surplus )  was  offset  by  a  corresponding  volume  of  remittances  from  over- 
seas Chinese.  Most  of  the  trade  was  with  the  United  Kingdom,  the  United 
States,  and  Western  Europe. 

THE  PROSPECT  FOR  COMMUNIST  CHINA 

The  description  given  in  the  foregoing  pages  has  revealed  a  nation  of 
great  size  and  population,  occupying  a  country  not  bountifully  endowed 
with  natural  resources,  with  an  underdeveloped  transport  system  and  with 
most  of  the  population  living  so  close  to  minimum  subsistence  levels  as  to 
preclude  any  accumulation  of  capital  on  a  scale  large  enough  to  permit 
modernization  and  industrialization  of  the  economy.  How  can  such  a 
country  hope  to  wield  any  power  in  the  struggle  between  the  Communist 
bloc  and  the  West,  at  least  for  a  long  period  of  time?  In  answering  this 
question  we  should  look  at  what  the  new  regime  has  done  to  date,  what 
it  proposes  to  do,  and  what  its  problems  are. 

Official  Chinese  figures  claim  an  impressive  rate  of  expansion  in  the 
industrial  sector  of  the  economy  since  the  completion  of  the  revolution  in 
1949.  In  addition  to  the  increases  in  output  reported  by  Chou  En-lai, 
quoted  above,  the  Chinese  Premier,  in  the  same  speech,  stated  that  the 
total  value  of  industrial  production  increased  from  1949  to  1952  at  an 
annual  average  rate  of  36.9  per  cent,  and  from  1952  to  1953  by  33  per 
cent.  He  predicted  that  the  total  value  of  modern  industrial  output  in 
1954  would  be  4.2  times  that  of  1949,  and  the  value  of  all  output  (indus- 
trial, agricultural,  and  handicraft)  2.2  times  that  of  1949.  Further,  Chou 
En-lai  claimed  that  the  ratio  of  modern  industrial  output  to  all  output 


508       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

increased  from  17  per  cent  in  1949  to  33  per  cent  in  1954,  and  the  ratio  of 
capital  goods  production  to  total  industrial  production  from  28.8  per  cent 
in  1949  to  42.3  per  cent  in  1954.  State-owned,  co-operative,  and  joint  state- 
and-private  enterprises,  according  to  Chou,  would  account  for  about  71 
per  cent  of  total  industrial  output  in  1954  compared  to  only  37  per  cent 
in  1949. 

These  claims  undoubtedly  exaggerate  the  expansion  going  on  in  the 
Chinese  economy,  considering  the  low  level  of  output  in  1949,  the  well- 
established  practice  of  Communist  statisticians  to  overstate  rates  of 
growth,  and  the  previous  poverty  of  economic  statistics  in  China.  What 
probably  lies  behind  these  statements  is,  nevertheless,  a  remarkable  rec- 
ord of  reconstruction  and  rehabilitation  of  the  economy,  plus  considerable 
progress  in  the  direction  of  nationalization  of  large  enterprises.  The  effects 
of  war  damage  and  civil  dislocation  on  production  had  probably  been 
eliminated  by  1952,  aided  by  good  harvests  in  1950,  1951,  and  1952.  Sub- 
stantial increases  in  output  were  made  in  steel,  cotton  textiles,  paper,  and 
other  consumers  goods,  while  pig  iron,  coal,  electric  power,  sugar,  soy- 
bean, and  wheat  production  remained  below  previous  peaks. 

In  addition  to  achieving  a  recovery  of  production,  the  Chinese  Com- 
munists may  be  credited  with  some  success  in  bringing  the  industrial 
economy  under  state  planning,  in  carrying  through  a  large-scale  program 
of  land  redistribution,  and  in  preparing  for  the  socialization  as  well  as  the 
industrialization  of  the  economy. 

In  the  third  year  of  the  first  five-year  plan  it  is  still  true  to  say  that 
China's  industrialization  is  just  beginning.  One  writer  has  compared  Com- 
munist China's  present  position  with  that  of  Japan  at  the  beginning  of  the 
Meiji  period.77  A  number  of  analysts  have  compared  China's  present  posi- 
tion unfavorably  with  that  of  the  U.S.S.R.  at  the  beginning  of  its  first  five- 
year  plan  in  1928.  In  1952  China  has  a  larger  industrial  base  than  Japan 
had  in  the  1860's  but  much  smaller  than  the  Soviet  Union's  in  1928.  The 
relation  between  resources  and  population  was  much  more  favorable  in 
the  Soviet  Union.  The  Soviet  Union  had  a  more  literate  and  more  skilled 
labor  force.  Finally,  the  Soviet  Union  did  not  then  need  to  devote  so  large 
a  portion  of  its  resources  to  military  expenditure. 

The  gross  national  product  of  Communist  China  in  1952  was  probably 
equivalent  to  not  more  than  thirty  billion  dollars  nor  less  than  twenty-five 
billion,  or  roughly  between  45  and  50  dollars  per  capita.  Recent  estimates 

77  W.  W.  Rostow  and  others,  The  Prospects  for  Chinese  Communist  Society  (Cam- 
bridge, 1954),  p.  320.  This  is  a  comprehensive  analysis  of  the  prospects  for  Chinese 
economic  development  based  on  studies  conducted  at  the  Center  for  International 
Studies,  Massachusetts  Institute  of  Technology. 


GROWING  ECONOMIC  STRENGTH  OF  SINO-SOVIET  BLOC     509 

by  Alexander  Eckstein  include  an  attempt  to  give  a  breakdown  of  the 
gross  national  product  by  source  and  use. 

TABLE   15-9 
China's  Gross  National  Product,  1952  * 


BY  ECONOMIC  ORIGIN 


PER  CENT 


BY  USE 


PER  CENT 


Agriculture 

40.0 

Household   Consumption 

73.0 

Small  scale  &  rural  industry 

15.0 

Govt.   Administration 

4.0 

Trade  and  Transport 

24.0 

Communal  Services 

4.0 

Factory  Industry  and  Mining 

7.0 

Military   Expenditures 

7.0 

Housing 

4.0 

Gross  domestic  investment 

12.0 

Government  and  other  Services 

10.0 
100.0 

100.0 

*  W.  W.  Rostow  and  others,  The  Prospects  jor  Chinese  Communist  Society  (Cambridge,  1954),  p.  350. 

If  these  approximations  are  correct  they  indicate  that  Communist  China 
already  has  mobilized  a  respectable  proportion  of  total  output  for  invest- 
ment, 12  per  cent  as  against,  say  5  to  8  per  cent  for  India.  And  the  figure 
for  investment  excludes  private  investment  (by  the  peasant,  small  pro- 
prietor, and  so  forth ) . 


CHINESE  COMMUNIST  ECONOMIC  GOALS 

In  Chou  En-lai's  speech  to  the  First  National  People's  Congress,  quoted 
above,  he  declares  confidently  that  "We  shall  certainly  be  able,  in  the 
course  of  several  five-year  plans,  to  build  China  into  a  strong  modern 
industrialized,  Socialist  nation."  There  are  abundant  signs,  however,  that 
the  Chinese  officials  are  not  blind  to  the  obstacles  that  lie  ahead,  in  the 
way  both  of  industrialization  and  of  the  transition  to  socialism.  Chou  him- 
self admits  that  many  of  the  details  of  the  first  five-year  plan  have  not 
been  worked  out,  that  the  Chinese  are  inexperienced  at  state  planning, 
that  the  industrial  foundation  is  weak,  that  skilled  labor  is  inadequate, 
and  that  industrial  management  is  poor.  He  also  appears  to  recognize  that 
development  of  more,  and  more  efficient,  agricultural  production  is  essen- 
tial to  provide  for  the  rapid  growth  in  population  and  for  the  release  of 
manpower  to  the  growing  urban  industries,  and  that  Soviet  economic  and 
technical  assistance  will  be  indispensable. 

The  short-run  goals  that  are  published  are  nevertheless  quite  ambitious. 
The  table  on  page  510  indicates  the  goals  established  for  the  first  five-year 
Plan. 

The  attainment  of  these  goals  would  give  China  a  crude  steel  capacity 


510       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

equal  to  that  of  the  U.S.S.R.  in  1928,  exceeding  that  of  Canada,  Belgium, 
and  other  small  countries  but  considerably  below  the  levels  attained  by 
Japan  in  the  1930's.  The  most  ambitious— and  dubious— features  of  the  first 
five-year  plan  is  in  agriculture,  calling  for  an  increase  of  30  per  cent  in 
grain  output  between  1953  and  1957.  Consideration  of  these  goals 
suggests  that  the  factors  most  crucial  to  success  or  failure  are  likely  to  be 
found  in  the  following:  ( 1 )  the  limitations  of  natural  and  human  resources 
to  growth  in  industrial  output;  (2)  whether  agricultural  production  can 
keep  pace  with  population  growth,  and  agricultural  productivity  keep 
ahead  of  the  demands  of  industry  for  man  power;  ( 3 )  whether  the  transi- 
tion to  socialism  will  interfere  with  expansion  of  output  (especially  in 
agriculture);  and  (4)  the  gains  to  be  had  from  foreign  trade  and  Soviet 
aid.  Let  us  consider  each  one  of  these  factors  in  somewhat  greater  detail. 

TABLE  15-10 

Industrial  Production  Targets  for  Communist  China  * 


INDEX 

OUTPUT 

PRODUCT 

1952  =  100 

UNITS 

1952 

TARGET " 

Crude  Steel 

400 

thousand  MT 

1,215 

4,860 

Rolled  Steel 

250 

C( 

740 

1,850 

Coal 

160 

et 

48,230 

77,170 

Electric  Power 

200 

million  kwh 

5,700 

11,400 

Mining  Equipment 

200 

n.a. 

n.a. 

n.a. 

Metal-cutting 

Machinery 

350 

n.a. 

n.a. 

n.a. 

a  No  exact  date  is  given,  but  it  refers  either  to  the  last  year  of  the  Plan,  1957,  or 'to  when  the  current 
aid  agreement  expires,  i.e.,  1959. 

*  Rostow  and  others,  op.  cit.,  p.  346,  from  Pravda,  September   28,   1953. 


THE  PROBLEM  OF  INDUSTRIAL  GROWTH 

In  the  present  phase,  because  of  the  head  start  given  by  Japanese  de- 
velopment, Manchuria  is  the  key  to  Chinese  industrial  expansion.78  In 
Manchuria  skilled  labor  is  more  plentiful,  transport  is  better,  iron  ore  is 
found  close  to  coal  and  non-ferrous  metals,  and  steel-using  industries  are 
in  operation.  Manchuria  has  over  two-thirds  of  known  Chinese  iron  re- 
serves. The  Communist  estimate  is  nearly  6  billion  tons.  Maximum  pro- 
duction probably  reached  5  million  tons  during  the  war.  The  ore  is  of  low 
quality  but  the  Japanese  earlier,  and  more  recently  the  Communists, 
claimed  to  have  found  higher-grade  ores.  Copper,  lead,  zinc,  magnesium, 
and  molybdenum  are  found  throughout  Manchuria.  Manchurian  coal  re- 
serves are  less  than  a  tenth  of  total  Chinese  reserves  but  they  produce 

78  The  Economist,  September  18,  1954. 


GROWING  ECONOMIC  STRENGTH  OF  SINO-SOVIET  BLOC     511 

about  one-half  of  current  output.  Penchihu  provides  the  best  coking  coal, 
and  together  with  Yentan  supplies  coal  both  for  its  own  iron  industry  and 
for  Anshan.  Good  quality  coal  is  found  in  the  Tunhua  region,  also  near 
rich  iron  ore  deposits.  The  coal  mine  in  Fushun  is  the  largest  open-pit 
mine  in  the  world.  This  coal  is  not  of  very  good  quality  but  it  can  be  used 
for  coking  if  mixed  with  Penchihu  coal.  On  balance,  the  1957  target  of 
100  million  tons  of  coal  production  does  not  seem  unlikely  of  attainment. 

Anshan,  Mukden,  and  Tunhua  are  the  principal  centers  of  industrial 
development.  Anshan's  pig  iron  output  is  reported  now  to  be  1.6  million 
tons  and  crude  steel  production  at  800,000  tons.  Doubling  of  these  rates, 
plus  the  addition  of  new  plants  at  Tunhua,  are  necessary  for  the  attain- 
ment of  the  1957  steel  production  goal  of  5  million  tons. 

Mukden,  already  the  center  for  railway  equipment,  is  scheduled  also  to 
be  the  principal  location  for  the  machine  tool  and  other  engineering  in- 
dustries. Chemical  and  engineering  industries  are  to  be  developed  in  Har- 
bin, Anshan,  Fushun,  and  Penchihu.  Manchuria  has  thus  the  potential  for 
a  considerable  further  development  of  metallurgy  and  heavy  industry. 
The  rate  at  which  this  development  will  go  forward  will  depend  more  on 
the  extent  of  Soviet  assistance  than  on  any  other  factor.  Estimates  made 
by  Eckstein  and  Rostow  indicate  that  the  investment  costs  of  the  steel  and 
electric  power  components  of  the  first  five-year  plan  would  be  in  the 
neighborhood  of  one  billion  United  States  dollars  of  which  about  one- 
third  would  represent  imported  equipment  that  would  presumably  have 
to  be  supplied  from  the  Soviet  Union.79  It  is  not  unlikely  that  Soviet  assist- 
ance will  be  concentrated  in  these  sectors.  Thus  the  attainment  of  the 
industrial  goals  by  1960  is  not  at  all  improbable. 


AGRICULTURAL  PRODUCTION  AND  POPULATION  GROWTH 

With  the  emphasis  on  public  health  and  sanitation,  mortality  rates  are 
now  likely  to  decline  sharply  in  China  as  they  have  in  India,  Ceylon, 
Egypt,  and  Mexico.  With  birth  rates  remaining  stationary  the  population 
of  China  may  now  be  expected  to  grow  more  rapidly,  probably  between 
1  and  2  per  cent  per  annum.80  This  means  that  Chinese  agriculture  will 
face  the  problem  of  expanding  total  output  to  keep  per  capita  consump- 
tion the  same.  In  addition  productivity  will  have  to  be  raised  if  man  power 
is  to  be  released  to  urban  industries,  and  raised  still  further  if  per  capita 
food  consumption  is  to  be  raised  from  its  present  very  low  levels. 

79  Rostow,  op.  cit.,  p.  348. 

80  See  above,  Ch.  9,  p.  325. 


512       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

There  are,  of  course,  two  ways  of  increasing  agricultural  output:  bring- 
ing more  land  under  cultivation  and  increasing  yields  per  acre.  Since  no 
more  than  about  15  million  acres,  equal  to  about  6  per  cent  of  land  pres- 
ently cultivated,  can  practicably  be  brought  to  produce  crops,  the  major 
reliance  will  have  to  be  placed  on  increasing  yields  per  acre.  Substantial 
increases  in  yields  are  possible  with  the  application  on  a  large  scale  of 
commercial  fertilizers.  However,  according  to  official  Chinese  Communist 
reports,  production  in  1952  of  ammonium  sulphate,  one  of  the  principal 
fertilizers  required,  was  only  about  350,000  tons,  whereas  to  raise  average 
crop  yields  by  25  per  cent  an  estimated  6.5  million  tons  would  be  required. 
It  would  almost  certainly  take  from  five  to  ten  years  for  production  even 
to  approach  the  required  levels  because  of  the  high  capital  costs  and  large 
requirements  for  electricity.81 

Other  measures  that  may  more  easily  be  introduced,  because  they  are 
labor  intensive  and  do  not  require  much  equipment,  include  seed  selec- 
tion, pest  control,  flood  control  and  water  conservation,  but  their  effect  on 
crop  yields  will  be  more  gradual  and  less  impressive  than  the  effects  that 
would  be  expected  from  the  widespread  use  of  commercial  fertilizers. 
Thus  Communist  China  is  even  more  likely  than  the  U.S.S.R.  to  have  diffi- 
culty in  expanding  food  production  to  keep  pace  with  the  growth  in  total 
population  and  in  the  urban  industrial  population. 

THE  SOCIALIST  TRANSFORMATION  OF  AGRICULTURE 

It  is  impossible  to  determine  what  effect  the  program  of  large-scale  land 
redistribution  put  in  effect  by  the  Communists  has  had  upon  output. 
About  30  to  40  per  cent  of  Chinese  farmers  before  the  revolution  were 
tenants  and  these  now  have  their  own  plots.  The  state,  however,  is  now 
an  efficient  and  determined  tax  collector,  and  through  the  party  apparatus, 
the  mutual  aid  teams  and  producers'  co-operatives  may  be  expected  to 
extract  the  food  supplies  needed  for  the  urbanized  areas.  The  incentives 
to  more  efficient  crop  production  from  land  ownership  may  thus  be 
eliminated.  In  any  case,  the  socialist  goal  is  collective  farming,  under 
which  many  of  the  incentives  of  private  land  ownership  will  disappear. 
There  are  signs  that  the  Chinese  Communists  are  approaching  this  task 
more  circumspectly  than  their  comrades  in  the  U.S.S.R.  whose  socialist 
designs  on  the  peasants  inflicted  damage  which  is  still  being  reflected  in 
Soviet  agricultural  production.  "In  order  that  agriculture  may  develop 

81  Rostow,  op.  cit.,  p.  334. 


GROWING  ECONOMIC  STRENGTH  OF  SINO-SOVIET  RLOC    513 

more  quickly  and  in  a  more  planned  way,  we  must  gradually  carry  out 
the  Socialist  Transformation."  82 

By  1953  about  one-half  of  the  rural  households  were  organized  in 
mutual  aid  teams,  and  about  273,000  households  were  organized  into 
14,000  producer  co-operatives.  By  1957  some  20  per  cent  of  all  farms 
would  be  members  of  such  co-operatives.83  It  is  too  early  to  be  able  to 
determine  when  the  next  stage,  that  of  full  collectivization,  will  be  intro- 
duced, or  at  what  rate  it  will  proceed.  The  co-operative  organization  of 
the  rural  economy,  together  with  other  forms  of  control  exercised  by  the 
state  and  party  apparatus,  is  probably  adequate  to  the  needs  of  the  regime 
so  far  as  extracting  the  maximum  share  of  farm  output  is  concerned. 
Collectivization  ->n  the  other  hand  will  be  designed  presumably  to  organ- 
ize for  greater  and  more  efficient  output,  and  while  it  could  take  place  in 
advance  of  mechanization,  it  is  not  likely  in  the  absence  of  mechanization 
to  have  much  effect  either  in  increasing  output  or  improving  productivity 
and  releasing  labor  for  industrial  employment.  Collectivization  may 
therefore  be  expected  to  proceed  as  and  when  farm  machinery  becomes 
available  in  significant  quantities.  In  the  meantime  the  goal  of  Chinese 
agrarian  policy  must  be  to  hold  down  consumption  on  the  farm. 

The  goal  of  a  30  per  cent  increase  in  grain  output  appears  quite  un- 
realistic for  the  reasons  given  above.  Whatever  increase  is  achieved,  how- 
ever, will  not  benefit  the  peasants  remaining  on  the  farms  but  is  more 
likely  to  be  pre-empted  for  the  growing  urban  industrial  population. 
Eckstein  has  constructed  a  model  showing  the  growth  of  the  Chinese 
economy  from  1952  to  1962  in  which  the  gross  national  product  increases 
from  the  equivalent  of  $30  billion  to  $41.2  billion  (at  constant  prices),  or 
about  37  per  cent,  but  in  which  aggregate  expenditure  on  personal  con- 
sumption increases  only  from  $22  billion  to  $26.7  billion  or  21  per  cent.84 
The  estimated  population  increase  during  this  period  is  from  582  million 
persons  to  654  millions  or  12  per  cent;  this  would  indicate  an  increase  in 
annual  per  capita  consumption  increasing  from  about  $38  to  $41.  Rural 
consumption  on  the  other  hand  is  estimated  in  the  model  to  increase  in  the 
aggregate  from  $14.7  billion  to  only  $15.1  billion,  while  rural  population 
grows  from  466  million  persons  to  479  millions.  The  result  is  no  increase 
in  per  capita  consumption  for  the  rural  population. 

The  significance  of  these  calculations  is  not  that  of  a  set  of  predictions 

82  Speech  of  Chou  En-lai,  October  1954. 

83  Rostow,  op.  cit.,  p.  337. 

84  Ibid.,  p.  353. 


514       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

but  of  an  attempt  to  express  quantitatively  the  conditions  of  the  kind  of 
economic  growth  the  Communist  regime  has  set  for  the  next  decade. 
Keeping  farm  consumption  down  will  help  to  increase  industrial  employ- 
ment and  investment;  gross  industrial  investment  in  the  same  model  in- 
creases from  4.8  per  cent  of  gross  national  product  to  over  8  per  cent  and 
industrial  output  from  7  per  cent  of  gross  national  product  to  almost  17 
per  cent.  These  projections  are  of  course  subject  to  a  number  of  hazardous 
assumptions  regarding  not  only  the  efficiency  of  the  capital  and  labor 
recruited  for  the  new  industrial  enterprises,  but  also  and  especially  the 
course  of  agricultural  production  in  the  absence  of  consumption  gains  for 
the  farmer.  But  the  response  of  the  Chinese  peasant  to  the  forced  and  un- 
rewarded reorganization  of  his  life  and  work  is  likely  to  be  more  important 
than  any  other  single  factor,  both  as  affecting  economic  growth  and  as 
a  test  of  the  determination  and  ruthlessness  of  the  new  regime.  In  the  light 
of  the  characteristic  stubbornness  of  peasant  resistance  to  change,  and 
especially  in  the  light  of  the  difficulties  experienced  in  the  Soviet  Union, 
one  may  conclude  that  while  the  political  control  of  the  regime  is  hardly 
in  danger,  its  program  of  economic  expansion  has  a  rough  road  ahead. 

FOREIGN  TRADE  AND  SOVIET  AID 

Up  to  1950  about  one-quarter  of  China's  trade  was  with  the  rest  of  the 
Soviet  bloc  and  three-quarters  was  with  the  rest  of  the  world.  By  1954 
these  proportions  were  reversed,  not  so  much  as  a  result,  of  the  United 
Nations  embargo  which  was  imposed  after  the  Chinese  invasion  of  Ko- 
rea, but  of  a  deliberate  policy  throughout  the  bloc  of  redirecting  trade 
inward. 

In  1953  exports  of  Communist  China  to  the  Free  World  were  about 
$434  million;  imports  from  the  Free  World  were  about  $284  million.  Trade 
with  the  Soviet  bloc  is  not  reported  but  is  probably  in  the  neighborhood 
of  $800  million  to  a  billion  dollars  each  way.  In  addition  to  its  own  exports 
to  the  Soviet  bloc,  China  probably  uses  its  visible  trade  surplus  with  the 
rest  of  the  world  to  pay  for  imports  from  the  Soviet  bloc.  The  commodity 
composition  of  the  trade  probably  remains  much  the  same  as  before,  with 
Communist  China  relying  on  the  U.S.S.R.  and  the  European  satellites  for 
the  machinery,  equipment,  and  manufactured  goods  formerly  obtained 
from  the  United  States,  Great  Britain,  and  Western  Europe.  There  is  little 
doubt  that  foreign  trade  plays  an  important  role  in  China's  development 
program  since  imports  supply  about  one-fifth  of  the  value  of  capital  for- 


GROWING  ECONOMIC  STRENGTH  OF  SINO-SOVIET  BLOC     515 

mation.  The  process  of  capital  formation,  in  other  words,  to  some  extent 
takes  the  form  of  extracting  an  exportable  surplus  of  raw  material  and 
agricultural  commodities  to  pay  for  imports  of  capital  goods.  But  increas- 
ingly China  is  relying  on  the  European  Soviet  bloc  to  supply  its  needs  for 
machinery  and  equipment,  and  engineering  and  technical  services.  In  fact 
the  rapid  modernization  of  China's  economy  is  inconceivable  without  such 
imports. 

The  U.S.S.R.  with  the  European  satellites,  especially  Poland,  Czecho- 
slovakia, and  East  Germany,  is  unquestionably  in  a  position  to  supply 
China  with  a  considerable  quantity  and  variety  of  capital  goods,  which 
can  be  transported  without  difficulty  either  by  sea  or  by  means  of  the 
Trans-Siberia  railway.  Because  China  is  the  weaker  of  the  two  trading 
partners,  the  terms  of  its  trade  with  the  U.S.S.R.  are  probably  less  favor- 
able than  if  it  could  follow  a  policy  of  buying  in  the  cheapest  market. 

Soviet  economic  aid  to  China  during  the  first  four  years  of  the  Commu- 
nist regime  was  substantial  but  by  no  means  massive.  Moreover,  the  aid 
consisted,  apparently  entirely,  of  credits  as  opposed  to  grant  aid.  In  1949 
the  Sino-Soviet  aid  agreement  provided  $300  millions  of  credits  and  in 
September,  1953,  the  U.S.S.R.  promised  to  help  build  141  projects,  "the 
sinews"  according  to  Chou  En-lai,  of  the  first  five-year  plan.  According  to 
unofficial  reports,  the  September,  1953,  agreement  called  for  a  ten-year 
aid  program  involving  total  aid  equal  to  one  billion  dollars  and  including 
the  $300  million  provided  in  the  1949  agreement.  Over  the  five-year  period 
the  annual  average  of  economic  assistance  provided  would  be  about  $117 
million.  This  would  be  less  than  10  per  cent  of  the  average  annual  net 
industrial  investment  projected  in  Eckstein's  model.85  Most  of  what  China 
requires  in  the  way  of  imported  capital  goods  from  the  Soviet  Union  will 
therefore  have  to  be  paid  for  with  imports. 

This  is  not  surprising,  for  it  would  appear  improbable  that  the  U.S.S.R. 
would  devote  any  considerable  amount  of  capital  resources,  even  against 
repayment,  to  the  task  of  awakening  the  strength  of  China's  600  million 
people,  when  those  resources  are  still  badly  needed  at  home.  But  the 
U.S.S.R.  may  well  be  reaching  the  point  where  it  is  advantageous  to  ex- 
port certain  types  of  capital  goods  in  exchange  for  badly  needed  agricul- 
tural commodities.  Thus,  the  pace  of  China's  industrialization  will  depend 
to  a  large  extent  on  its  ability  to  expand  exports  of  raw  materials  and 
foodstuff,  either  by  increasing  output  or  by  restricting  consumption,  or  by 
a  combination  of  both. 

85  Ibid.,  p.  353. 


516       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

CONCLUSIONS 

The  Economic  Potential.  China  is  an  immense  country  with  the  largest 
population  in  the  world.  It  is  a  very  poor  country  with  a  primitive  agricul- 
ture, very  little  industry,  an  underdeveloped  transportation  system,  and 
not  overly  well-endowed  with  natural  resources.  Its  present  power  rests 
in  its  numbers,  and  its  potential  power  in  the  ruthless  determination  of 
a  communist  dictatorship  to  mobilize  both  the  people  and  the  resources, 
at  whatever  cost,  to  build  the  economic  base  both  for  an  industrialized 
communist  state  and  for  great  power  status. 

Communist  China's  weakness  lies  also  in  its  numbers  in  their  relation 
to  available  resources,  for  this  relationship  is  so  unbalanced  that  it  will  be 
difficult  to  produce  the  surplus  of  agricultural  output  needed  to  feed  the 
growing  numbers  of  the  urban  industrial  labor  force. 

It  has  been  pointed  out  that  to  achieve  the  Communist  economic  goals 
the  following  conditions  must  be  met:  86 

1.  A  high  proportion  of  industrial  output  must  be  reinvested  in  industry. 

2.  An  increasing  proportion  of  national  output  must  be  allocated  to  exports 
in  return  for  imports  of  raw  materials,  machinery  and  military  equipment. 

3.  An  increased  volume  of  agricultural  output  must  be  allocated  (a)  to 
exports  and  (b)  to  feeding  the  growing  urban  population. 

4.  An  increasing  proportion  of  total  output  must  be  devoted  to  investment, 
and  increases  in  consumption  and  welfare  must,  except  for  urban  indus- 
trial workers,  be  postponed. 

To  meet  all  these  conditions  will  be  difficult.  And  even  if  they  are  met 
progress  will  be  slow  in  relation  to  the  continuing  growth  of  the  indus- 
trialized states  of  the  West.  Because  of  the  low  level  of  departure  for 
China,  the  gap  between  its  expanding  capabilities  and  those  of  the  United 
States  and  Western  Europe  will,  in  absolute  terms,  continue  to  widen  for 
many  years.  In  comparison,  however,  with  other  countries  of  East  Asia, 
unless  their  development  too  is  accelerated,  the  progress  made  by  Com- 
munist China  will  furnish  an  impressive  example. 

The  Sino-Soviet  Bloc  Today  and  in  the  Future 

We  have  given  this  chapter  the  title  "The  Growing  Economic  Strength 
of  the  Sino-Soviet  Bloc";  at  this  point  we  should  draw  the  balance  of  our 
discussion  on  economic  power  factors  and  potentials  in  both  the  Soviet 
Union  and  Communist  China  to  try  to  evaluate  the  factors  of  strength  and 

86  Rostow,  op.  cit.,  Ch.  15. 


GROWING  ECONOMIC  STRENGTH  OF  SINO-SOVIET  BLOC     517 

weakness  which  this  bloc  of  the  two  main  Communist  powers  of  our  time 
reveals.  The  Chinese-Russian  alliance  came  into  effect  in  February,  1950. 
It  has  proved  its  stability  in  the  Korean  War.  The  common  goals  of  the 
two  Communist  nations  have  been  given  practical  expression;  in  October, 
1954,  the  two  governments  issued  joint  declarations  on  general  questions 
of  Chinese-Soviet  relations  with  Japan;  the  U.S.S.R.  agreed  to  evacuate 
the  Port  Arthur  naval  base  and  to  transfer  it  without  compensation  to 
China;  the  Soviet-Chinese  shareholding  societies  which  were  set  up  in  1950 
and  1951  for  mining  and  oil  refining  purposes  were  transferred  by  mutual 
agreement  to  China;  scientific-technical  collaboration  and  the  building  of 
the  Lanchow-Urumchi-Alma-Ata  railway  were  mutually  agreed  upon.  In 
the  latter  case,  the  two  governments  agreed  that  both  sides  should  begin 
the  building  of  this  line  on  Chinese  and  Soviet  territory,  and  they  also 
agreed  to  continue  the  plans  for  the  building  of  the  railroad  between 
Tsining  in  China  and  Ulan  Bator  in  the  territory  of  the  Mongolian  Peoples 
Republic,  which  is  to  be  linked  with  the  railway  running  from  Ulan  Bator 
to  Soviet  territory.  At  the  end  of  1955,  considerable  progress  had  been 
achieved  in  the  construction  of  the  strategic  rail  links  through  Sinkiang 
and  Outer  Mongolia  which  will  constitute  new  lines  of  communication 
between  the  U.S^S.R.  and  North  and  Central  China,  supplementing  the 
Trans-Siberian  line  in  the  north.  Such  lines,  when  completed,  will  facili- 
tate the  movement  of  goods  between  China  and  the  U.S.S.R.  They  will 
also  make  it  much  easier  in  time  of  war  to  move  military  equipment  and 
supplies  to  central  and  southern  China,  on  lines  which  would  be  invulner- 
able to  naval  blockade  and  relatively  secure  against  airborne  attacks 
launched  from  bases  and  naval  craft  off  the  coast  of  China.  Eventually  they 
will  also  facilitate  the  development  of  new  and  less  exposed  industrial 
centers  in  the  Hinterland.87 

It  thus  appears  that  at  the  time  these  lines  are  written,  the  links  between 
the  two  nations  are  strong  and  will  be  further  strengthened.  However,  in 
comparing  the  two  partners  we  must  not,  in  the  over-all  economic  ap- 
praisal, lose  sight  of  the  fact  that  China  as  a  partner  of  the  U.S.S.R.  ap- 
pears to  be  in  the  state  of  infancy.  Its  strength  lies  in  the  future,  and  a 
comparison  of,  for  instance,  the  steel  and  coal  production  data  of  the  two 
countries  shows  the  weak  position  of  China  as  against  that  of  the  U.S.S.R. 
There  is  no  likelihood  of  competitive  conflicts  in  the  near  future.  How- 
ever, when  and  if  these  new  developments  lead  to  the  appearance  of  an 
industrially  and  militarily  strong  Chinese  power  along  the  Asian  bounda- 
ries of  the  Soviet  Union,  tensions  and  frictions  may  well  be  the  conse- 

»7  See  p.  485,  and  Fig.  15-2,  p.  478. 


518       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

quence.  They  may  be  increased  by  the  fact  that  China,  whose  population 
of  close  to  600,000,000  people  far  surpasses  that  of  the  Soviet  Union  with  a 
population  of  about  210  million  people,  is  and  will  be  the  strongest  propo- 
nent of  a  persuasive  "Asia  for  the  Asians"  program.  This  force  may  be- 
come a  factor  of  ominous  importance  and  should  not  be  neglected  in  the 
over-all  appraisal  of  the  economic  power  potentials  of  the  two  Commu- 
nist nations. 


CHAPTER 


16 


Japan's  Economy 


In  this  section  of  the  book  we  are  attempting  to  assess  the  economic 
capabilities,  not  of  all  the  countries  of  the  world,  but  only  of  those  major 
countries  and  area  groupings  whose  actual  or  potential  strength  must  be 
reckoned  with  in  any  attempt  to  calculate  the  world  balance  of  political 
power.  In  any  such  attempt  some  attention  must  be  given  to  Japan. 

There  are  several  reasons  for  this.  In  the  first  place,  Japan  has  been  for 
some  time  the  only  Asian  country  with  the  economic  capabilities  for  great 
power  status.  Such  a  statement  sounds  surprising  now  that  we  are  accus- 
tomed to  think  of  Communist  China  as  the  major  military  power  in  the 
Far  East.  But  it  must  not  be  overlooked  that  the  military  strength  demon- 
strated by  Communist  China  in  the  Korean  war  depended  essentially  on 
Soviet  logistical  support.  A  decade  or  more  ago,  when  the  cost  of  defeating 
Japan  in  World  War  II  was  fresh  in  the  memories  of  the  American  people, 
no  one  thought  of  China  as  capable  of  creating  a  modern  military  estab- 
lishment on  a  large  scale  for  many  years  to  come,  while  Japan  had  been 
a  formidable  enemy  with  a  modern  air  force,  a  large  well-equipped  army 
and  the  world's  third  largest  navy. 

What  has  happened  to  alter  these  superficial  impressions?  On  the  one 
hand  is  the  notion  that  Japan's  economy  was  hopelessly  crippled  by  war 
damage  and  the  loss  of  empire,  and  that  Japan's  almost  90  million  people, 
confined  to  the  home  islands,  remain  dependent  on  American  aid.  On  the 
other  hand  is  the  widespread  but  somewhat  exaggerated  view  that  under 
Communism  China's  industrial  power  has  grown  so  rapidly  that  economi- 
cally as  well  as  militarily  China  is  now  a  modern  state  and  one  of  the 
world's  few  great  powers. 

519 


.__. — ., 


uS 


I 


SEA  OF 
JAPAN 


180  Mi 


0        60       120      180  Km 


Fig.  16-1.  Japan:  Industrial  Areas  and  Selected  Railroads. 


520 


JAPAN'S  ECONOMY  521 

At  present,  of  course,  China  has  an  overwhelming  superiority  in  mobi- 
lized ground  forces,  while  the  sheer  mass  of  its  population  constitutes  a 
vast  and  perhaps  unalterable  advantage.  Otherwise,  the  balance  of  eco- 
nomic capabilities  still  lies  with  Japan,  as  a  comparison  of  the  chief 
economic  indicators  will  quickly  show.  With  a  population  of  around  88 
million,  Japan  had  a  gross  product  of  about  $15  billion  in  1952  compared 
with  about  $30  billion  for  Communist  China's  almost  600  million  souls. 
Japan  produced  43.2  million  tons  of  coal;  China  48.2  million.  Japan  pro- 
duced 7  million  tons  of  steel;  China  1.2.  Japan  produced  almost  52  billion 
kilowatt  hours  of  electricity  while  China  produced  only  5.7  billion.1 
Moreover,  Japan  had  an  extensive  road  and  rail  communication  network 
(Fig.  16-1),  a  diversified  manufacturing  and  heavy  capital  goods  industry, 
and  a  skilled  labor  force.  These  accomplishments  combined  to  make  Japan 
still  the  leading  industrial  power  in  Asia. 

By  Western  standards,  however,  Japan  had  never  achieved  a  high  state 
of  development.  This  is  reflected  in  comparative  per  capita  gross  national 
product  which  in  Japan  was  the  equivalent,  in  1954  of  about  $230.  In  the 
United  States  per  capita  gross  national  product  was  $2,280  in  1954;  in  the 
United  Kingdom,  $911;  in  West  Germany,  $674;  and  in  Argentina,  $650. 
But  even  with  such  a  comparatively  low  level  of  income,  Japan  was  once 
able  to  mobilize  an  impressive  surplus  for  military  and  strategic  purposes. 

The  relative  abundance  in  Japan— as  contrasted  with  the  rest  of  Asia— 
of  the  things  which  characterize  a  modern  industrial  economy  is  due  to 
the  remarkable  speed  with  which  the  Japanese  economy  was  transformed 
after  the  Meiji  restoration  in  1868,  a  process  which  provides  another 
reason  for  studying  Japan's  economic  capabilities.  This  transformation 
was  the  result  of  a  deliberate  decision  to  modernize  Japan's  economy, 
a  decision  remarkable  for  its  explicit  recognition  of  the  vital  connection 
between  economic  capabilities  and  military  power. 

The  Shogunate  policy  of  isolation  had  been  discredited,  more  than  any- 
thing else,  by  the  performance  of  western  cannon  in  the  naval  bombard- 
ments of  Kagoshima  and  Shimonoseki  in  1863  and  1864,  convincing  proof 
that  Japan  would  never  be  secure  until  the  Japanese  could  provide  them- 
selves with  modern  weapons.2  Recognition  of  this  fact  by  a  certain  group 
of  feudal  princes  led  to  the  repudiation  of  the  Shogunate  in  1868,  the 
restoration  of  the  emperor,  and  the  abolition  of  feudalism.  The  new  gov- 

1  Figures  for  Japan  from  UN,  Economic  Commission  for  Asia  and  the  Far  East 
(ESCAFE),  Economic  Survey  of  Asia  and  the  Far  East,  1954  (Bangkok,  1955);  for 
China  from  Rostow,  op.  cit.,  p.  297. 

2  C.  J.  H.  Hayes,  A  Political  and  Social  History  of  Modern  Europe  (New  York, 
1929),  p.  579. 


522        THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

ernment  expressly  assumed  responsibility  for  the  modernization  and  Eu- 
ropeanization  of  Japan.  Armed  forces  were  established  on  western  models, 
and  the  necessary  supporting  industries  were  brought  into  being  with  the 
aid  of  government  subsidies  and  western  advisors.  Neighboring  islands 
were  acquired:  the  northern  and  central  Kuriles  in  1875,  the  Bonins  in 
1876,  the  rest  of  the  Ryukyus  in  1878.  Formosa  was  acquired  in  1895  as 
one  of  the  spoils  of  the  war  with  China. 

By  1904,  only  thirty-six  years  after  the  establishment  of  the  first  small 
arms  arsenal  at  Tokyo,  the  Japanese  entered  the  war  with  Russia  with 
6  modern  battleships,  8  cruisers,  80  torpedo  boats,  19  destroyers  and  other 
vessels.  This  war,  especially  the  naval  phase,  was  a  decisive  victory  for 
the  Japanese,  and  although  Japan  was  almost  exhausted  at  its  end,  it  gave 
Japan  the  standing  of  a  world  power.  It  is  true  that  many  of  the  vessels 
of  this  fleet  had  been  constructed  abroad,  but  their  possession  itself  is 
witness  to  a  remarkable  expansion  of  the  Japanese  economy,  involving 
construction  of  railways,  the  development  of  ocean  shipping,  the  creation 
of  steel,  textile,  and  other  industries,  and  a  rapid  expansion  of  foreign 
trade. 

This  growth  continued  after  the  Russo-Japanese  war.  The  population, 
which  had  been  about  35  million  in  1873  rose  to  45.5  million  in  1903, 
56  million  in  1920,  and  73.1  million  by  1940.  Industrial  production  in- 
creased by  almost  five  times  between  1907  and  1931  and  rose  by  a  further 
80  per  cent  between  1931  and  1937. 

Japan's  decisive  victory  over  Russia  encouraged  further  aggrandize- 
ment. Korea  was  annexed  in  1910.  Japan's  role  in  World  War  I  was  re- 
warded by  the  mandates  of  the  Marshall,  Caroline,  and  Mariana  islands. 
Manchuria  was  acquired  in  1932,  and  the  war  against  China  began  in 
1937.  Japan  thus  built  up  an  overseas  empire  to  supply  it  with  foodstuffs 
and  raw  materials  lacking  at  home  and  to  provide  markets  in  return  for  the 
products  of  Japanese  consumer  goods  and  light  manufacturing  industries. 
Korea  supplied  rice,  Formosa  rice  and  sugar,  Manchuria  metallic  ores  and 
soybeans,  Sakhalin  lumber  and  wood  products,  the  Kuriles  fish  and  other 
marine  products.  Thus  did  Japan's  colonial  policy  aim  at  overcoming  the 
resource  deficiencies  of  the  home  islands.3 

Much  of  these  gains  might  have  been  preserved  to  Imperial  Japan  if  not 
for  the  overconfident  attack  on  the  United  States  in  1941.  The  defeat  of 
Japan  in  World  War  II  has  for  practical  purposes  reduced  Japan  to  the 
four  main  islands  of  Honshu,  Kyushu,  Shikoku,  and  Hokkaido.  It  is  upon 

3Cf.  G.  D.  H.  Cole,  World  in  Transition  (New  York,  1949),  pp.  462-463  for 
related  aspects  of  Japanese  policy. 


JAPAN'S  ECONOMY  523 

these  islands  and  their  resources  that  the  Japanese  are  trying  to  rebuild 
a  viable  economy  and  a  secure  state.  As  a  result  of  the  loss  of  Japan's 
colonial  empire,  Japan,  with  a  vastly  increased  population,  has  been 
thrown  back  to  the  resources  base  which  it  controlled  at  the  beginning  of 
its  expansion  in  the  second  half  of  the  nineteenth  century.  In  addition  to 
this  limitation,  Japan  has  now  to  compete  with  India's  slowly  growing 
industrial  capacity  and  with  the  unified  military,  political,  and  economic 
power  of  a  China  no  longer  under  the  influence  of  the  West. 

JAPAN'S  LAND  AND  PEOPLE 

Postwar  Japan  contains  147,611  square  miles,  about  the  size  of  Califor- 
nia.4 In  addition  to  the  four  main  islands  there  are  hundreds  of  smaller 
islands  emphasizing  Japan's  essentially  insular  character.  No  place  is  more 
than  a  few  score  miles  from  the  sea  and  there  is  one  mile  of  coastline  for 
every  8.5  square  miles  of  area.  Living  thus  in  the  presence  of  the  sea  the 
Japanese,  like  the  English,  have  become  good  sailors  and  fishermen  and, 
as  with  the  English,  fish  is  an  important  item  in  the  diet  and  second  only 
to  rice.  Foreign  trade  is  indispensable  to  the  economy. 

Japan  is  as  mountainous  as  it  is  insular.  The  level  area  does  not  exceed 
70,000  square  miles  and  not  all  of  this  is  arable.  Rivers  are  short,  steep, 
and  generally  unsuited  for  navigation. 

Japan's  location,  roughly  from  30°  to  45°  north  latitude,  gives  it  a 
generally  temperate  climate,  but  this  statement  is  subject  to  important 
modifications.  The  islands  extend  about  one  thousand  miles  from  south- 
west to  northeast  and  are  subject  to  both  continental  and  marine  influ- 
ences. In  the  summer,  winds  from  the  Pacific  (the  summer  monsoon) 
warmed  by  the  Kuroshio  current  bring  warm  rainy  weather;  the  winter 
monsoon  from  Eastern  Asia,  bringing  cold  air  and  moisture  from  the  sea 
of  Japan,  is  responsible  for  heavy  snowfall  in  Hokkaido  and  northwestern 
Honshu.  All  of  Japan  has  adequate  rainfall,  the  seasonal  and  geographical 
distribution  depending  on  relief  and  the  monsoon. 

On  the  plains,  in  the  valleys,  and  on  the  hillsides  of  these  narrow  islands 
live  almost  90  million  people.  This  population  is  concentrated  in  the 
coastal  plains,  the  area  of  greatest  population  extending  from  the  Kwanto 
plain  around  Tokyo  along  the  Pacific  coast  line  to  the  Inland  Sea.  But 
wherever  the  land  is  not  too  steep  and  the  soil  reasonably  fertile  there  are 

4  For  a  more  extended  discussion  of  Japan's  geography  see  Cressey,  op.  cit.,  pp. 
166-231.  The  basic  works  are  G.  T.  Trewartha,  Japan,  A  Physical,  Cultural  and  Re- 
gional Geography  (Madison,  Wisconsin,  1945),  and  G.  H.  Smith  and  D.  Good  with 
S.  McCune,  Japan,  A  Geographical  View  (New  York,  1943). 


524       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

people.  Population  density  is  almost  600  people  per  square  mile,  but  since 
only  about  13  per  cent  of  the  total  area  is  cultivated,  there  are  over  4,000 
people  for  each  square  mile  of  cultivated  land.  About  half  of  the  labor 
force  is  engaged  in  agriculture  and  fishing,  and  many  of  those  engaged  in 
non-agricultural  pursuits  return  to  the  farm  during  periods  of  unemploy- 
ment. In  1947  there  were  204  cities  of  over  25,000  people,  but  only  six 
cities  of  over  500,000  (with  a  total  population  of  8,175,367).  Although  it  is 
the  chief  industrial  economy  of  Asia,  Japan  is  still  largely  rural  or  at  least 
non-urban  in  character.  This  is  underlined  by  the  fact  that  from  the  end  of 
World  War  II  to  1955  the  net  movement  of  persons  from  the  cities  to  the 
rural  districts  reached  a  total  of  4,000,000  persons. 

Japan's  population  has  undergone  a  rapid  expansion  since  the  end  of 
the  Shogunate.  Population  was  fairly  stable  under  the  Tokugawa  regime 
( 1602-1867)  at  around  26  million,  but  rose  rapidly  after  the  Meiji  restora- 
tion and  had  doubled  by  1925.  In  1937  the  population  was  about  70  mil- 
lion, and  in  1948,  80.2  million,  the  difference  being  due  not  so  much  to 
natural  increase  as  to  the  repatriation  of  some  6  million  overseas  Japanese 
at  the  end  of  the  war.  In  1955,  the  population  was  estimated  at  89 
million,  the  latest  census  having  been  in  1950.  The  rate  of  increase  is  now 
around  1  per  cent  annually,  much  lower  than  in  earlier  decades,  and 
Japan's  population  may  be  nearing,  though  it  certainly  has  not  attained, 
stability.  Over  the  next  decade  the  population  may  be  expected  to  increase 
by  9  or  10  million. 

NATURAL  RESOURCES 

Japan  is  poorly  endowed  with  mineral  resources.5  Many  minerals  are 
present,  but  only  a  few  such  as  coal,  copper,  zinc,  and  sulphur  are  present 
in  anything  like  adequate  quantities.  The  shortage  of  minerals  is  fre- 
quently cited  in  extenuation  of  Japan's  expansionary  adventures  in  the 
twentieth  century,  even  though  Japan's  own  industrial  development, 
achieved  on  the  basis  of  imported  supplies  of  many  raw  materials,  illus- 
trates the  falsity  of  the  premise.  Japan  has  no  nickel,  aluminum,  or  mag- 
nesium, and  iron  ore  is  both  insufficient  and  of  low  quality.  Most  coking 
coal  must  be  imported.  Copper  is  Japan's  most  important  metallic  mineral 
and  is  occasionally  exported;  zinc  is  fairly  plentiful  and  there  is  some 
production  of  lead,  tin,  and  chromium. 

For  energy  Japan  has  enjoyed  adequate  supplies  of  steam  coal,  but  the 
best  seams   are  nearing   exhaustion   and   becoming   increasingly   costly. 

5  See  the  comprehensive  work  by  E.  Ackerman,  Japanese  Natural  Resources 
(Tokyo,  1949). 


JAPAN'S  ECONOMY  525 

Petroleum  reserves  are  insignificant  and  95  per  cent  of  requirements  are 
imported.  A  large  part  of  Japan's  total  energy  supply  comes  from  hydro- 
electric power,  but  most  good  hydro-electric  sites  have  already  been  ex- 
ploited. Japan  may  thus  be  one  of  the  first  countries  in  which  atomic 
power  production  will  become  economically  feasible. 

GENERAL  FEATURES  OF  THE  ECONOMY 

In  Japan,  the  modern  industrial  economy,  concentrated  in  a  few  urban 
centers  and  depending  on  foreign  trade  for  raw  materials  and  markets, 
has  been  superimposed  on  the  traditional  economy  in  which  small-scale 
labor,  intensive  agriculture,  and  handicraft  industries,  supplying  the  do- 
mestic market,  account  for  a  large  proportion  of  employment.  Before  the 
Meiji  restoration,  Japan  was  almost  completely  independent  of  foreign 
trade,  with  little  or  no  mechanized  industry.  Three  quarters  of  the  work- 
ing population  were  engaged  in  agriculture.  Textile  production  was  a 
small-scale,  handicraft  industry.  Metal  production  was  primitive.  After  the 
opening  up  of  Japan,  the  new  government  saw  the  problem  of  moderniz- 
ing the  national  economy  not  so  much  as  the  problem  of  developing  a 
surplus  (as  would  be  the  case  with  many  underdeveloped  countries  to- 
day) as  that  of  converting  an  agricultural  surplus  (rice,  tea,  silk  and  silk 
worms)  into  the  means  to  pay  for  imports  of  modern  machinery  and 
equipment.  The  surplus  was  extracted  from  a  docile  agricultural  popula- 
tion by  taxation  and  high  rents,  at  first  in  kind  but  before  long  in  money. 
During  the  early  stages  of  Japan's  development  the  major  exports  were 
raw  silk,  tea,  and  rice,  accounting  for  about  two-thirds  of  the  total.  As  the 
population  increased,  rice  disappeared  from  the  export  list,  and  Japan 
now  imports  large  quantities  of  foodstuffs,  but  textile  products— first  raw 
silk  and  later  cotton  yarn  and  piece  goods— provided  the  bulk  of  Japan's 
exports.  It  was  not  until  the  thirties,  when  Japan  embarked  on  the  creation 
of  a  war  economy,  that  intensive  development  of  the  metal,  machinery, 
and  chemicals  industries  was  undertaken.6  Thus  a  peasant  economy  de- 
veloped into  an  industrial  one  by  first  exporting  the  products  of  agricul- 
ture to  obtain  the  machinery  and  equipment  needed  to  produce  light 
manufactured  and  semi-finished  goods.  As  the  export  of  the  latter  in- 
creased, that  of  the  former  declined  and  Japan  shifted  from  exporting  to 
importing  food  and  raw  materials. 

This  process,  however,  was  not  carried  as  far  in  Japan  as,  for  example, 

6  See  G.  Allen,  A  Short  Economic  History  of  Modern  Japan  (London,  1946),  esp. 
pp.  143-160. 


526       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

in  the  United  Kingdom,  and  a  large  part  of  Japan's  working  population 
are  still  engaged  in  agriculture.  Out  of  a  total  of  41  million  persons  em- 
ployed in  1954,  about  19  million  were  employed  in  agriculture,  forestry 
and  fishing,  as  compared  with  between  6  and  7  million  in  manufactur- 
ing.7 On  the  other  hand  the  value  of  output  in  manufacturing  (1,421 
billion  yen  in  1953 )  exceeds  that  of  agriculture,  forestry  and  fishing  ( 1,300 
billion  yen),  reflecting  the  much  greater  efficiency  of  the  modern  indus- 
trial sector  of  the  economy. 

Japan's  agriculture  is  small  scale:  about  three-quarters  of  the  arable 
land  is  farmed  by  peasants  8  whose  average  holding  is  about  three 
acres.9  The  chief  food  grain  is  rice,  grown  all  over  the  southern  part  of 
Japan  and  utilizing  about  60  per  cent  of  the  total  arable  land.  Japanese 
rice  production  in  1954  was  about  11.8  million  tons.  Wheat,  rye,  and  bar- 
ley utilize  about  30  per  cent  of  all  arable  land.  Wheat  production  in  1954 
was  about  1.5  million  tons.  Yields  per  acre  are  relatively  high  (reflecting 
large  inputs  of  labor  and  fertilizer ) ,  and  yet  about  20  per  cent  of  Japan's 
food  grain  requirements  must  be  imported.  Thus  further  increases  in 
population  will  require  imports  of  foodstuffs,  since  there  is  little  or  no 
remaining  uncultivated  arable  land.  Tea  is  another  important  Japanese 
crop  and  is  exported  in  quantity  to  the  United  States.  Raw  silk,  produced 
by  wheat  farmers,  is  also  an  important  crop  and  once  was  Japan's  chief  ex- 
port. Now  it  accounts  for  less  than  10  per  cent  by  value  of  Japan's  total 
exports.  Sweet  potatoes  are  an  important  food  crop  for  domestic  consump- 
tion. About  1.5  million  persons  are  employed  in  the  fisheries,  and  fish  is— 
with  rice— the  staple  food,  with  a  total  value  exceeding  that  of  the  British 
fishing  industry.  In  fact,  Japan  leads  all  other  countries  in  the  number  of 
persons  engaged  in  the  fisheries,  the  size  of  its  fleets  and  the  volume  of 
catch.10  Canned  and  frozen  fish  are  also  an  important  export,  and  the 
Japanese  fishing  fleets  operate  not  only  in  Japanese  and  nearby  waters, 
but  seek  fish  and  whales  in  distant  seas.  As  a  result,  Japan  is  frequently 
involved  in  international  conflicts  arising  out  of  actual  and  alleged  viola- 
tions of  foreign  territorial  waters  by  her  fishing  vessels.  A  case  in  point  is 
the  fishing  issue  between  Japan  and  the  Republic  of  Korea  which  accuses 
Japan  of  violations  of  the  so-called  Rhee  Line,  a  unilaterally  set  water 
boundary  extending  more  than  sixty  miles  from  the  Korean  coast. 

7  United  Nations,  Economic  Survey  of  Asia  and  the  Far  East,  1954  (Bangkok, 
1955),  Table  12,  p.  218. 

8  D.  Stamp,  An  Intermediate  Commercial  Geo°raplu/  (London,  1954),  Part  2, 
p.  409. 

9  Cressey,  op.  cit.,  196. 

10  Woytinsky,  op.  cit.,  p.  727. 


JAPAN'S  ECONOMY  527 

The  industrial  sector  of  Japan's  economy  includes  a  wide  range  of 
textiles,  iron  and  steel  products,  machinery  and  transportation  equipment, 
chemicals  and  chemical  fertilizers.  Emphasis  however,  is  on  textiles, 
which  in  1953  accounted  for  about  30  per  cent  of  Japan's  total  exports. 
Production  of  cotton  yarn  in  1952  amounted  to  353,100  tons  compared 
with  268,100  tons  in  the  UK,  292,400  in  West  Germany,  and  724,700  tons 
in  India.  Japan  also  produces  cotton,  silk  and  woolen  fabrics,  and  a  wide 
range  of  manufactured  consumer  goods  such  as  pottery  and  china,  glass, 
paper,  matches,  and  toys.  Production  of  some  basic  industrial  commodities 
and  services  in  1953  is  given  in  the  table  below.11 


COMMODITY 

QUANTITY 

UNIT 

Coal 

46.5 

million  tons 

Petroleum  products 

6.1 

//          // 

Iron  ore 

1.5 

//          // 

Steel  Ingots  and  Metal 

7.7 

//              r/ 

Cement 

8.8 

rr             // 

Electricity 

55.7 

billion  kwh 

Sulphuric  Acid 

4.3 

million  tons 

Ammonium  sulphate 

2.0 

n           tr 

Superphosphate 

1.5 

//             tr 

Industrial  production  in  Japan  is  concentrated  in  a  belt  extending  from 
Tokyo  and  the  Kwanto  plain  in  the  east  along  both  shores  of  the  Inland 
Sea  to  northern  Kyushu  and  the  western  entrance  of  the  Inland  Sea  (cf. 
Fig.  16-1,  p.  520).  Small  factories  producing  native  goods— silks,  lacquer- 
ware,  toys,  and  Japanese  paper— are  still  active  in  the  villages  and  towns, 
but  modern  factories  are  concentrated  in  or  near  the  large  cities,  especially 
the  six  largest  cities  of  Tokyo,  Yokohama,  Nagoya,  Kobe,  Osaka,  and 
Kyoto.  Textile  production  is  concentrated  in  the  Kobe-Osaka  region, 
while  heavy  industry  tended  to  be  concentrated  in  the  northern  Kyushu 
region,  near  the  coal  fields  and  convenient  to  western  ports  for  imports  of 
iron  ore  and  pig  iron  that  used  to  come  from  Manchuria. 

As  indicated  above,  the  Japanese  economy  is  heavily  dependent  on  im- 
ports, not  only  of  food  grains  and  sugar  but  even  more  of  raw  materials 
such  as  raw  cotton  for  the  cotton  spinning  industry,  iron  ore  and  coking 
coal  for  the  steel  industry,  and  petroleum.  In  the  inter-war  period  imports 
of  these  commodities  were  paid  for  by  exports  of  raw  silk,  especially  to 
the  United  States,  and  of  cotton  textiles  to  less  developed  countries  in 
Asia  and  Latin  America.  Imports  from  Japanese  overseas  possessions  such 
as  sugar  from  Formosa,  iron  ore  from  Manchuria,  and  rice  from  Korea, 

11  United  Nations,  Economic  Survey  of  Asia  and  the  Far  East. 


528       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

were  obtained  in  exchange  for  textiles,  other  consumer  goods  and  capital 
equipment.  This  trade  accounted  for  42  per  cent  of  Japan's  exports  in 
1936.  In  the  postwar  period,  the  United  States  market  for  silk  had 
dwindled,  the  overseas  possessions  were  gone,  and  trade  with  the  China 
mainland  dried  up,  partly  because  of  Western  export  controls  but  mainly 
because  under  the  Communists  China's  trade  was  reoriented  to  the  Soviet 
bloc.  In  addition  Japanese  exports  encountered  political  barriers  in  many 
markets  and  increasing  competition  from  locally  produced  goods.  Japan's 
share  of  total  world  trade  was  sharply  reduced. 

During  the  occupation  period,  before  Japan's  export  industries  had 
recovered  from  the  effects  of  the  war,  necessary  imports  (especially  cot- 
ton, wheat,  coal,  and  iron  ore)  were  supplied  by  the  United  States  to  the 
extent  of  Japan's  inability  to  pay.  From  1946  to  1949  such  payments,  for 
which  the  United  States  claims  partial  repayment,  amounted  to  about  $2 
billion.  Since  the  end  of  the  occupation  Japan  has  continued  to  have  a 
substantial  deficit  on  merchandise  trade  account,  but  procurement  in 
Japan  for  the  account  of  United  States  troops  stationed  there  and  for  the 
United  Nations  Forces  in  Korea  has  occasioned  foreign  exchange  pay- 
ments to  Japan  sufficient  to  balance  Japan's  accounts  without  further 
assistance.  These  special  earnings  amounted  to  almost  $3  billion  in  the 
years  1951  to  1954  inclusive. 

Roughly  40  per  cent  of  Japan's  exports  in  1953  went  to  the  dollar  area, 
25  per  cent  to  the  sterling  area,  and  35  per  cent  to  countries  with  whom 
Japan  had  bilateral  trade  arrangements.  By  contrast,  over  50  per  cent  of 
Japan's  imports  have  been  coming  from  the  dollar  area  against  only  25 
per  cent  from  the  sterling  area  and  about  20  to  25  per  cent  from  other 
areas.  Thus  Japan's  trade  and  payments  problem  is  also  to  a  large  extent 
a  dollar  problem  because  surpluses  that  might  be  earned  in  trading  with 
the  sterling  or  other  areas  cannot  generally  be  applied  to  offset  the  deficit 
with  the  dollar  area. 


PRESENT  POSITION  AND  PROSPECTS 

Japan's  economy  has  made  a  remarkable  recovery  from  the  effects  of 
war  and  postwar  adjustments.  Despite  the  20  per  cent  increase  in  popula- 
tion since  before  the  war  and  despite  the  loss  of  empire,  industrial  pro- 
duction is  well  above  the  prewar  level.  Per  capita  consumption  of  practi- 
cally everything  except  possibly  housing,  and  labor  productivity  are  equal 
to  or  above  prewar  levels.  Agricultural  production  however  has  not  kept 


JAPAN'S  ECONOMY  529 

pace  with  the  population  increase,  and  present  food  consumption  levels 
depend  on  increased  imports. 

As  indicated  above,  Japan's  economic  problem  in  the  short  run  is  that 
of  increasing  exports  sufficiently  to  balance  its  current  accounts  without 
the  aid  of  special  procurement  expenditures  by  the  United  States.  In  the 
long  run,  however,  the  problem  is  that  of  increasing  exports  to  pay  for 
increased  imports  of  foodstuffs  and  raw  materials.  It  has  been  estimated 
that  Japan's  food  grain  requirements  increase  each  year  by  200,000  tons 
merely  to  feed  new  mouths.  Without  radical  improvements  in  agricultural 
technology,  Japan  cannot  meet  any  considerable  portion  of  these  in- 
creased requirements  except  through  imports,  since  yields  per  acre  are 
very  high  and  there  is  relatively  little  unused  or  reclaimable  land.  In- 
creased exports  will  require  increased  imports  of  raw  materials  entering 
into  such  exports.  And  higher  levels  of  income  will  generate  demands  for 
larger  and  more  varied  diets  and  for  other  goods  utilizing  imported  raw 
materials.  Thus  Japan  must  strive  continually  for  higher  levels  of  trade, 
based  on  increased  production  of  exportable  goods  and  high  levels  of 
investment. 

There  are  good  reasons  for  believing  that  Japan  can  restore  viability 
and  the  necessary  dynamism  to  its  economy.  Output  has  been  increasing 
at  an  impressive  rate  and  investment  is  maintained  at  a  proportion  of 
income  that  compares  favorably  with  Western  countries  enjoying  much 
higher  per  capita  incomes.  The  people  of  Japan  are  industrious  and  thrifty 
as  well  as  literate  and  technically  skilled.  While  the  land  and  labor  reforms 
introduced  under  the  Occupation  have  to  some  extent  redistributed  in- 
come progressively,  Japan  is  relying  on  its  own  peculiar  forms  of  private 
enterprise  and  is  likely  to  avoid  expensive  or  risky  welfare  schemes  and 
to  pursue  conservative  monetary  and  fiscal  policies.  Thus  needed  incen- 
tives to  improvement  and  modernization  of  obsolete  plant  and  equipment 
will  likely  continue  to  be  present. 

As  indicated  above,  the  big  problem  for  Japan  will  lie  in  the  field  of 
foreign  trade.  Some  progress  has  already  been  shown  in  increasing  Japan's 
share  of  certain  export  markets,  notably  in  Latin  America.  It  is  not  as  easy 
to  see  how  Japan  will  find  alternative,  non-dollar,  sources  of  imports  that 
formerly  came  from  the  United  States  or  mainland  Asia.  The  natural 
sources  of  these  foodstuffs  and  raw  materials  for  Japan  would  seem  to  be 
in  South  and  Southeast  Asia,  and  Japan's  capital  goods  can  contribute  to 
the  development  of  export  availabilities  in  these  areas. 

Despite  Japan's  industrial  superiority  in  Asia  and  its  not  unprepossess- 


530       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

ing  outlook,  Japan's  actual  military  capabilities  are  slight.  However,  Japan 
is  recovering  rapidly  from  what  has  been  called  the  trauma  of  defeat  and 
Japanese  forces  will  undoubtedly  be  strengthened.  Nevertheless,  there  is 
still  considerable  opposition  to  large  forces,  both  as  unrealistic  in  the 
nuclear  age  and  as  requiring  diversion  of  resources  needed  for  moderni- 
zation and  expansion  of  Japan's  export  industries. 


CHAPTER 


17 


The  Economic  Capabilities  or 
Western  Europe 


A.    Introduction 

Europe  is  the  smallest  of  the  continents;  with  an  area  of  three  and  three- 
fourths  million  square  miles  it  has  only  one-fifth  of  the  land  area  of  Asia.1 
Indeed,  from  the  viewpoint  of  physical  geography  it  is  a  mere  extension— 
a  peninsula— of  a  larger  land  mass  to  which  the  term  Eurasia  is  properly 
applied.  Nevertheless,  because  of  radical  differences  in  historical  devel- 
opment, cultural  background,  and  political  outlook  between  East  and 
West  it  is  customary  to  treat  the  larger  area  as  two  continents,  roughly 
separated  by  a  boundary  consisting  of  the  Ural  mountains,  the  Caspian 
Sea,  the  Caucasus,  and  the  Black  Sea.  And,  as  Mackinder  pointed  out,  in 
contrast  with  "the  unbroken  lowland  of  the  east,"  the  European  peninsula 
is  a  "rich  complex  of  mountains  and  valleys,  islands  and  peninsulas."  2 

This  complex  is  one  of  the  three  or  four  great  centers  of  population  and 
industrial  activity  in  the  world.  In  the  nineteenth  century  it  experienced 
a  phenomenal  expansion  in  population  and  production,  and  five  European 
states  (Great  Britain,  France,  Germany,  Belgium,  and  the  Netherlands) 
acquired  among  them  political  control  over  almost  all  of  Africa  and  Asia 
except  Japan,  China,  and  what  is  today  the  Soviet  Far  East.  By  means  of 
education  and  the  press,  even  more  by  reason  of  the  prestige  which  ac- 

1  J.  Stembridge,  The  World:  A  General  Regional  Geography  (London,  1953),  p.  97. 

2  H.  J.  Mackinder,  The  Geographical  Pivot  of  History,  reprinted  with  an  intro- 
duction by  E.  W.  Gilbert,  Royal  Geographic  Society  (London,  1951),  p.  31. 

531 


532       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

companied  the  extension  of  European  political  and  military  sway,  the 
cultural  and  political  values  of  Europe  came  to  dominate  almost  the 
whole  world.  And  the  world  economy,  with  its  trade  and  shipping,  its 
banking  and  insurance  services,  the  gold  standard  and  related  currencies, 
was  a  European  creation.  The  nineteenth  century  was  indeed  the  Euro- 
pean age. 

It  is  true  that  during  the  nineteenth  century  Russia  was  expanding  east- 
ward, taking  over  the  unpeopled  spaces  of  Siberia  and  creating  an  empire 
of  contiguous  possessions,  but  the  full  implications  of  this  expansion,  as  of 
the  westward  expansion  of  the  United  States,  were  not  realized  until  after 
the  first  World  War.  It  is  true  also  that  the  nineteenth  century  witnessed 
the  final  liquidation  of  the  Spanish  and  Portuguese  empires  in  America. 
Nevertheless,  the  last  three  decades  of  the  century  were  a  period  of  phe- 
nomenal territorial  expansion  and  conquest  for  the  European  powers,  and 
the  world  power  of  Europe  was  at  its  height  at  the  death  of  Queen  Vic- 
toria in  January,  1901. 

A  few  comparisons  will  suffice  to  show  how  vast  were  the  social  and 
political  changes  that  transformed  the  character  of  Europe  between  1800 
and  1900  (or  1914).  After  remaining  static  for  centuries,  the  population 
of  Europe  began  to  grow  rapidly  in  the  eighteenth  century  and  even  more 
rapidly  in  the  nineteenth.  The  population  of  Europe  as  a  whole  was  about 
50  million  in  1800,  246  million  in  1880,  and  316  million  in  1910.  At  the 
beginning  of  the  nineteenth  century,  as  elsewhere  in  the  world,  most  of 
the  population  were  engaged  in  agricultural  pursuits  and  lived  in  small 
towns  or  villages  and  rural  areas.  At  the  beginning  of  the  twentieth  cen- 
tury in  most  countries  of  northern  and  central  Europe,  the  majority  of 
people  were  employed  in  nonagricultural  pursuits  and  lived  in  towns  and 
cities.  This  shift  of  population  density  to  the  cities  was  a  reflection  of  the 
degree  of  industrialization  that  had  taken  place  in  Great  Britain,  Belgium, 
and  Germany,  and  to  a  lesser  extent  in  France,  the  Netherlands,  and  other 
countries.3 

The  nineteenth  century  was  also  a  period  of  extraordinary  colonial  ex- 
pansion in  Asia  and  Africa.  From  1884  to  1896,  in  twelve  years,  2.6  million 
square  miles  were  added  to  the  British  Empire,  bringing  the  total  to  about 
11.3  million  square  miles  in  all,  almost  one-fourth  of  the  land  area  of  the 
world.4  At  the  opening  of  the  twentieth  century  Britain  governed  a  third 
of  the  whole  population  of  Asia.  France  built  up  an  empire  in  Indo- 

3  See  Ch.  I,  "Industrial  Foundations  of  Contemporary  Europe,"  in  C.  J.  H.  Hayes, 
Contemporary  Europe  Since  1870  (New  York,  1953). 

4  E.  Halevy,  A  History  of  the  English  People,  trans,  by  E.  I.  Watkin  (London, 
1939),  Epilogue,  Vol.  I,  p.  30. 


THE  ECONOMIC  CAPABILITIES  OF  WESTERN  EUROPE        533 

China.  The  Dutch  extended  and  consolidated  their  control  over  the  East 
Indies  and  in  1914  ruled  over  some  54  million  Asians.  British,  German, 
and  French  enclaves  were  added  to  that  of  the  Portuguese  in  China.  And 
the  partition  of  Africa  in  the  last  two  decades  of  the  nineteenth  century 
gave  the  British,  French,  Belgians,  and  Portuguese  substantial  territories. 
Germany  belatedly  carved  out  a  colonial  empire  in  East  Africa,  the  Cam- 
eroons,  and  Southwest  Africa,  but  lost  it  to  the  victors  in  the  World  War 
of  1914-18. 

The  importance  of  economic  factors  in  any  imperialist  expansion  is 
always  difficult  to  assess  and  it  would  be  foolish  to  try  to  explain  the 
scramble  for  colonies  by  the  European  great  powers  in  the  nineteenth 
century  as  motivated  simply  by  the  desire  for  new  markets,  or  the  pres- 
sure of  surplus  funds  seeking  investment.  Nevertheless  there  is  no  doubt 
that  the  leading  statesmen  of  Europe  were  sufficiently  impressed  by  popu- 
lar ideas  of  the  importance  of  potential  colonies  as  markets,  raw  material 
sources,  and  outlets  for  investment  to  act  before  it  became  too  late.  Jules 
Ferry,  French  cabinet  leader  and  champion  of  the  cause  of  France's  new 
empire,  put  the  argument  in  its  most  extreme  form:  "European  consump- 
tion is  saturated:  it  is  necessary  to  raise  new  masses  of  consumers  in  other 
parts  of  the  globe  else  we  shall  put  modern  society  into  bankruptcy  and 
prepare  for  the  dawn  of  the  twentieth  century  a  cataclysmic  social  liqui- 
dation of  which  one  cannot  predict  the  consequences."  5 

To  speak  of  consumption  being  saturated,  even  in  the  France  of  today, 
is  of  course  absurd;  whatever  truth  there  is  in  Ferry's  prophecy  does  not 
depend  on  the  evident  falsity  of  his  economics.  The  twentieth  century  is 
witnessing,  for  France  and  other  colonial  powers,  the  United  Kingdom, 
and  the  Netherlands,  not  a  cataclysmic  social  liquidation,  but,  along  with 
other  important  political  and  social  changes,  the  liquidation  of  the  colo- 
nial empires  built  up  in  the  nineteenth  century.  Germany,  we  have  noted, 
lost  its  empire  as  a  result  of  the  first  World  War.  The  Dutch  lost  most  of 
their  East  Indies  possessions  after  the  second.  Britain  has  surrendered 
India  and  Burma,  France  is  losing  (or  has  lost)  Indo-China.  European 
influence  and  control,  except  for  tiny  Macao  and  Hong  Kong  have  been 
excised.  Everywhere  the  symbols  of  colonialism  are  challenged  and  de- 
cried; the  European  age,  as  the  title  of  one  book  suggests,  is  passing. 

The  history  of  European  imperialism  in  the  nineteenth  century  and  its 
liquidation  in  the  twentieth  lies  outside  the  scope  of  our  inquiry.  If  our 
theme  were  the  economic  history  of  imperialism,  we  would  analyze  care- 

5  Quoted  by  E.  Achorn,  European  Civilization  and  Politics  since  1815  (New  York, 
1934),  p.  246. 


534       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

fully  the  relation  between  these  processes  of  expansion  and  contraction, 
on  the  one  hand,  and  the  underlying  economic  capabilities  on  the  other. 
But  we  would  find  no  simple,  unilinear  relationship.  It  must  not  be 
thought  that  the  loss  of  empire  reflects  nothing  more  than  a  sapping  of 
economic  strength,  the  onset  of  economic  decay.  In  absolute  terms  the 
economies  of  Western  Europe  are  stronger,  their  production  and  con- 
sumption higher,  than  ever  before.  But  it  was  no  accident  that  European 
overseas  expansion  occurred  after  a  rapid  expansion  in  industrial  produc- 
tion and  transportation  which  enabled  the  powers  to  confront  native 
rulers,  in  Annam  and  Tonkin,  in  Madagascar,  in  China,  in  Algiers,  with 
overwhelming  force.  The  Japanese  learned  this  lesson  quickly  and  put  it 
to  effective  use  themselves.  Likewise  it  was  no  accident  that  independence 
came  to  India  and  Burma.  Pakistan  and  Syria,  Egypt  and  Indonesia,  at 
a  time  when  the  economies  of  the  metropolitan  countries  were  not  only 
recoiling  under  the  impact  of  war  and  occupation,  but  facing  new  claims 
on  resources  from  more  welfare-minded  citizens. 

No  doubt  the  most  important  factors  have  been  in  the  realm  of  ideas 
and  the  imagination.  The  moral  and  cultural  prestige  of  Europe  tended  to 
fall  with  the  introduction  of  European  ideas  abroad.  The  submission  of 
the  Asian  or  African  to  the  European's  right  to  rule  disappeared  with  the 
spread  of  ideas  of  democracy,  nationalism,  equality,  and  social  justice. 
The  basis  of  European  superiority  was  destroyed  when  members  of  the 
subject  races  learned  the  secrets  of  Western  science  and  technology  and 
decided,  rightly  or  wrongly,  that  the  industrial  revolution  would  come  to 
their  countries  under  their  own  sponsorship.  But  the  Opportunities  to 
assert  their  countries'  independence  came  at  the  low  ebb  of  European 
economic  strength  in  the  decade  after  World  War  II. 

We  have  merely  sketched  the  leading  role  the  industrialized  countries 
of  Europe  played  in  the  nineteenth  and  early  twentieth  centuries.  What 
will  be  the  role  of  Europe  in  the  world  economy  of  the  next  half-century? 

Despite  the  loss  of  important  overseas  possessions,  and  even  though 
now  outdistanced  by  the  growth  of  the  American  and  Soviet  economies, 
Western  Europe  has  not  wholly  lost  its  dynamism.  The  economies  of 
Western  Europe  continue  to  grow  and  in  the  aggregate  they  make  a  major 
contribution  to  the  strength  of  the  Free  World.  It  is  this  contribution  and 
its  geographical  and  economic  basis  that  we  examine  in  this  chapter. 

Our  method  is  to  look  first  at  the  economic  geography  and  the  economic 
structure  of  Western  Europe.  With  the  factual  information  thus  provided 
we  shall  then  examine  the  dynamic  factors  in  Western  Europe's  economy 
and  their  implications  for  the  future  growth  of  economic  capabilities. 


THE  ECONOMIC  CAPABILITIES  OF  WESTERN  EUROPE        535 

B.    Geographical  Features  of  Western  Europe 

Peninsular  Europe  would  include  both  the  countries  of  Western  and 
Northern  Europe  and  the  U.S.S.R.  and  Eastern  Europe  in  an  unmistakable 
geographical  unity.  According  to  H.  B.  George,  physical  geography  would 
divide  Europe  into  some  dozen  sections:  Spain  (with  Portugal),  Gaul,  the 
British  Isles,  Rhone-land,  Rhineland,  Italy,  Balkan-land,  Danube-land, 
North  Germany,  Bohemia,  Russia,  and  Scandinavia.6  Wright  employs  a 
simpler  classification  of  four  main  subdivisions,  but  his  Alpine-Mediter- 
ranean region  would  include  much  of  Balkan-land,  while  East  Germany, 
Poland,  and  Russia  fall  into  his  Northeastern  Europe.7  In  recent  years, 
however,  it  has  become  common  to  treat  the  whole  of  the  U.S.S.R.  sepa- 
rately and  to  exclude  Russia  when  discussing  European  geography  and 
politics.  In  addition,  for  our  purposes  we  must  limit  the  concept  of  Europe 
even  further  and  focus  on  what  is  now  called  Western  Europe,  since  the 
expansion  of  the  Soviet  bloc  has  engulfed  the  countries  of  Eastern  Europe, 
the  Balkans  ( except  Greece  and  Yugoslavia )  and  the  Baltic  countries  in  a 
new  political  unity.  Nor  is  this  merely  a  new  political  dividing  line  cutting 
across  a  geographical  unity;  the  countries  of  Eastern  Europe  were  for- 
merly bound  by  trade  and  cultural  ties  with  Western  Europe,  and  Europe 
formed  a  close-knit  economic  system,  whereas  now  the  cultural  and  eco- 
nomic life  of  Eastern  Europe  has  been  closed  off  from  the  West  and  its 
trade  has  been  largely  reoriented  to  the  Soviet  economy. 


WHAT  IS  WESTERN  EUROPE? 

This  division  of  Europe  into  East  and  West  is  likewise  reflected  in  the 
postwar  organization  of  political  and  economic  life  in  Western  Evirope, 
for  under  the  Marshall  Plan  co-operative  measures  to  restore  trade  and 
production  to  normal  levels,  to  strengthen  currencies  and  liberalize  trade, 
and  to  broaden  markets,  resulted  in  the  formation  of  a  number  of  new 
international  economic  planning  and  consultative  bodies,  such  as  the  Or- 
ganization for  European  Economic  Co-operation  (OEEC),  the  European 
Payments  Union  (EPU),  and  the  Coal-Steel  Community  (CSC).  Thus 
it  is  now  possible  for  certain  purposes  to  define  Western  Europe  by  mem- 
bership in  OEEC.  This  has  an  additional  convenience  because  the  OEE 
is  now  the  central  source  and  co-ordinating  agent  for  many  of  the  eco 


6  The  Relations  of  Geography  and  History  (London,  1930),  p.  118. 

7  J.  K.  Wright,  The  Geographical  Basis  of  European  History  (New  York,   1928). 
p.  4. 


536       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

nomic  statistics  of  the  member  countries.  More  will  be  said  of  these  or- 
ganizations later  in  the  chapter. 

OEEC  includes  Austria,  Belgium,  Denmark,  France,  Federal  (West) 
Germany,  Greece,  Iceland,  Ireland,  Italy,  Luxembourg,  The  Netherlands, 
Norway,  Portugal,  The  Saar,  Sweden,  Switzerland,  Trieste,  Turkey,  and 
the  United  Kingdom.  Spain  is  not  a  member  of  the  OEEC,  nor  is  Yugo- 
slavia, whereas  Turkey,  The  United  Kingdom,  Ireland,  and  Iceland  are. 
Except  for  the  United  Kingdom  these  omissions  and  inclusions  need  not 
detain  us,  even  though  they  may  appear  anomalous  geographically,  be- 
cause in  any  case  they  would  not  greatly  affect  the  statistical  measures  of 
economic  capabilities.  The  British  Isles,  separated  late  in  geological  time 
from  continental  Europe  by  the  straits  of  Dover,  and  strongly  influenced 
by  this  geographical  position,  has  been  in  the  last  two  centuries  the  center 
of  a  world-wide  political  and  economic  community.  Nevertheless,  in  this 
chapter  the  United  Kingdom  is  considered  to  be  part  of  Western  Europe. 
Not  only  is  this  convenient  because  the  United  Kingdom  is  a  member  of 
OEEC  and  included  in  Western  Europe  for  statistical  purposes;  the 
United  Kingdom  as  a  member  of  the  North  Atlantic  Treaty  Organization 
( NATO )  is  one  of  the  keystones  in  European  defense  arrangements  and 
therefore  must  be  counted  in  when  we  are  analyzing  Western  Europe's 
economic  capabilities. 

More  important  than  these  organizations  in  relation  to  political  and 
strategic  factors  are  the  groupings  of  Western  European  states  for  military 
purposes.  Membership  in  NATO  therefore  is  another  way  of  defining 
Western  Europe,  especially  when  one  is  measuring  and  comparing  the 
capabilities  of  those  countries  co-operating  in  the  Western  European  de- 
fense arrangements.  This  group  is  smaller  than  the  OEEC  group,  since 
Austria,  Sweden,  Switzerland,  and  Ireland  are  members  of  the  latter  but 
not  the  former.  The  continental  core  of  European  defense  comprises  a  still 
smaller  group  of  countries  seeking  to  find  some  basis  of  union  or  federa- 
tion for  defense  purposes:  France,  West  Germany,  Italy,  the  Saar,  Bel- 
gium, Luxembourg,  and  The  Netherlands.  They  now  constitute  what  is 
known  as  the  Western  European  Union. 

The  Europe  with  which  we  deal  in  this  chapter,  therefore,  is  Europe 
minus  Bussia,  the  Baltic  countries,  Poland,  Czechoslovakia,  Hungary, 
Bumania,  Bulgaria,  Albania,  and  East  Germany.  In  addition  to  the  con- 
tinental countries  of  Western  Europe  we  shall  include  the  United  King- 
dom and  Ireland,  Iceland  (but  not  Greenland),  and  Turkey.  With  these 
exceptions,  the  area  which  we  are  describing  has  the  same  boundaries  as 
the  continental  Europe  of  customary  geographical  descriptions :  the  Atlan- 


THE  ECONOMIC  CAPABILITIES  OF  WESTERN  EUROPE        537 

tic  Ocean  and  the  North  Sea  on  the  west,  the  Mediterranean  on  the  south, 
and  the  Arctic  Ocean  on  the  north.  It  was  always  the  eastern  boundary 
which  gave  geographers  trouble,  in  any  case,  and  the  boundary  which  has 
now  been  established  by  the  Iron  Curtain  is  not  without  a  certain  limited 
geographical  sanction,  for  it  coincides  very  roughly  with  the  climatic 
boundary  between  the  coastal  climate  of  Western  Europe  and  the  conti- 
nental climate  of  Central  and  Eastern  Europe.8 

Except  for  parts  of  Norway,  Sweden,  and  Finland,  Western  Europe  lies 
entirely  in  the  Temperate  Zone.  But  Western  Europe's  situation  and  shape 
influence  its  climate  favorably,  perhaps  more  than  its  latitudinal  position. 
Its  location  in  the  westerly  variable  wind  belt  and  the  absence  of  a  north- 
south  mountain  barrier  mean  that  the  moderating  influence  of  the  Atlantic 
Ocean  is  borne  a  considerable  distance  inland.  Europe  has  the  longest 
coast  line  in  relation  to  its  area  of  any  of  the  continents,  and  no  part  of 
Western  Europe  is  farther  than  500  miles  from  the  sea.9  There  is  conse- 
quently sufficient  rainfall  for  cultivation  almost  everywhere  in  Western 
Europe  except  the  interior  of  Spain,  and  it  is  well-distributed  throughout 
the  year.  In  the  west  and  northwest  autumn  rains  predominate;  summer 
rains  are  greatest  in  the  eastern  part  of  the  region.  In  the  south  of  Europe 
the  mountain-sheltered  peninsular  countries  that  form  the  northern  coast 
of  the  Mediterranean  experience  the  dry  summers  and  warm  rainy  win- 
ters associated  with  that  name. 

PHYSICAL  FEATURES  AND  COMMUNICATION  LINES 

Northern  Europe  is  separated  from  the  Mediterranean  regions  by  a 
formidable  chain  of  mountains,  the  Pyrenees,  the  Alps,  the  Carpathians, 
and  associated  lesser  ranges.  Running  south  from  these  mountains  are  the 
folds  of  the  Apennines,  forming  the  backbone  of  Italy,  and  the  Dinaric 
Alps  and  Pindus  Mountains.  North  of  this  barrier  are  the  central  uplands 
including  the  dry  Spanish  meseta,  the  central  plateau  of  France,  the 
highlands  of  Brittany,  Cornwall,  and  southwest  Ireland,  the  Ardennes  and 
the  Rhine  highlands,  and  the  Vosges  and  Black  Forest  ranges  on  either 

8  For  example,  the  line  marking  the  western  limit  of  average  below-freezing  surface 
temperatures  in  January  (D.  Stamp,  The  World  [New  York,  1943],  Fig.  112).  "The 
32°  F  winter  line  runs  from  Iceland  to  northern  Norway,  along  the  coast  to  Denmark, 
south  to  the  Alps,  then  east  to  the  Caspian  Sea.  ...  A  line  from  Salonika  to  northwest 
Germany  will  have  almost  all  the  winter  rainfall  of  over  10  inches  on  the  west  side 
and  that  of  less  than  10  inches  on  the  east— the  dry  continental  interior."  G.  D.  Hub- 
bard, The  Geography  of  Europe,  2nd  ed.   (New  York,  1952),  pp.  30-32. 

9  For  a  survey  of  Europe's  physical  geography  see  Stembridge,  op.  cit.,  Ch.  10,  and 
Hubbard,  op.  cit.,  Chs.  1,  2,  and  3. 


538       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

side  of  the  Rhine  valley.  North  of  these  uplands,  in  turn,  is  the  great 
European  plain,  stretching  from  the  Atlantic  Coast  of  France  across  the 
Lowlands  and  Germany,  Poland,  and  Russia.  This  extensive  and  fertile 
plain  not  only  accounts  for  the  high  proportion  of  arable  land  in  Europe; 
it  has  made  for  an  ease  of  communications  which  has  facilitated  the  in- 
dustrial expansion  of  northern  and  western  Europe.10  The  plentiful  and 
year-round  rainfall  provides  an  even  flow  of  water  in  the  rivers,  and  this 
plus  the  level  character  of  the  plain  has  resulted  in  waterways  being 
extensively  used  for  transportation  of  goods.  The  river  systems  have  been 
extended  and  interconnected  by  canals  ramifying  through  France,  Bel- 
gium, and  the  Rhine  valley.  While  most  of  this  traffic  originates  or  termi- 
nates at  Channel  or  North  Sea  ports,  two  rivers  connect  western  and 
central  Europe  with  the  south,  the  Rhone  flowing  into  the  Mediterranean 
at  Marseille,  and  the  Danube,  navigable  in  normal  times  for  over  1,500 
miles  from  Ulm  in  Western  Germany  to  the  Black  Sea.  In  recent  years, 
however,  the  Danube  has  in  its  lower  reaches  been  denied  to  Western 
European  traffic  by  the  Iron  Curtain. 

The  terrain  and  climate  of  the  United  Kingdom  similarly  favored  exten- 
sive use  of  inland  waterways,  and  its  coast  line  and  location  in  respect  to 
other  countries  of  northern  and  western  Europe  provided  the  natural  con- 
ditions for  coastal  and  other  shipping. 

The  sinking  of  the  continent  bv  allowing  the  ocean  to  extend  through  the  North 
Sea  into  the  Baltic  has  opened  up  the  heart  of  North-West  Europe  .  .  .  the  lower 
courses  of  many  rivers  have  been  converted  into  estuaries,  at  the  head  of  which 
now  stand  some  of  the  world's  greatest  ports.  In  the  south  the  Mediterranean 
and  Black  Seas  provided  a  sea-way  extending  more  than  2,000  miles  from  the 
Atlantic  while  the  Adriatic  arm  of  the  Mediterranean  provided  an  outlet  for  the 
southern  part  of  Central  Europe.11 

Altogether,  the  peninsular  character  of  Europe,  with  its  inland  seas, 
well-developed  coast  lines,  protected  bays  and  harbors,  and  many  navi- 
gable rivers  constituted  the  basis  of  an  extensive  and  economical  water 
transport  system.  It  is  not  hard  to  understand  why  foreign  trade  bulks  so 
large  in  the  economies  of  Western  Europe. 

NATURAL  RESOURCES 

This  sketchy  resume  of  the  "geographical  conditions"  of  Western  Eu- 
rope would  be  incomplete  without  some  reference  to  the  natural  resources 

10  L.  D.  Stamp  and  S.  C.  Gilmour,  Chisholm's  Handbook  of  Commercial  Geography, 
1 4th  ed.  (New  York,  1954),  pp.  316,  317. 

11  Stembridge,  op.  cit.,  pp.  97,  98. 


THE  ECONOMIC  CAPABILITIES  OF  WESTERN  EUROPE        539 

upon  which  the  economic  development  of  these  countries  rests,  those 
"treasures  of  field,  forest  and  mine  bestowed  upon  her  by  a  moister  cli- 
mate, a  more  varied  land  surface  and  a  more  complex  geological  past."  12 

First  must  be  mentioned  the  resources  of  the  soil  and  vegetation,  for 
Europe  was  once  largely  agricultural.  Most  of  Western  and  Central  Eu- 
rope were  once  covered  by  deciduous  woodlands,  long  since  cleared  for 
cultivation.  As  noted  earlier,  the  proportion  of  agricultural  land  is  higher 
in  Europe  (37  per  cent)  than  in  any  other  continent.  The  ratio  is  10  per 
cent  in  North  and  Middle  America,  6  per  cent  in  Asia,  and  5  per  cent  in 
South  America.  This  high  proportion  is  due  in  part  to  the  level  character 
of  the  European  plain,  and  in  part  to  the  fact  that  almost  four-fifths  of  the 
land  area  of  Europe  receives  adequate  (10  inches  or  more  annually) 
rainfall,  as  compared  to  one-third  in  North  America,  30  per  cent  in  Asia, 
and  one-fourth  in  Africa.  Only  the  South  American  continent  compares 
favorably  in  adequacy  of  rainfall  and  its  distribution.13 

While  Western  Europe  still  depends  importantly  on  its  intensive  agri- 
culture, it  is  no  exaggeration  to  say  that  its  mineral  resources  are  even 
more  important,  since  Western  Europe  as  a  whole  now  imports  agricul- 
tural goods  and  exports  manufactures  ( Fig.  17-1 ) .  Western  Europe's 
extensive  deposits  of  coal  and  iron  ore  were  the  key  to  its  industrial  de- 
velopment, and  are  the  essential  base  for  its  manufacturing  industries. 
British  coal  mines  still  produce  one-fifth  of  the  world's  coal,  although  the 
better  veins  have  been  worked  out.  Outside  the  United  Kingdom,  the 
principal  coal  deposits  are  the  Franco-Belgian  fields,  and  the  Ruhr.  Unfor- 
tunately, there  are  no  coal  mines  of  importance  in  southern  Europe.  Iron 
ore,  however,  is  well-distributed  in  Europe,  with  the  richest  ores  in 
Sweden  and  northern  Spain.  Most  of  the  iron  ore  is  produced  in  France, 
the  United  Kingdom,  Sweden,  and  Luxembourg,  in  that  order. 

Production  and  reserves  of  some  other  important  minerals  are  substan- 
tial, especially  tungsten,  bauxite,  lead,  zinc,  mercury,  and  sulphur.  Spain 
and  Italy  produce  about  two-thirds  of  the  world  supply  of  mercury.  Italy 
is  the  second  largest  producer  of  sulphur,  and  Spain,  Western  Germany, 
and  Yugoslavia  each  produce  more  than  50,000  tons  of  lead  annually. 
Copper  and  tungsten  are  produced  in  moderate  amounts,  and  nickel  in 
small  amounts.  Manganese  and  chromite  are  practically  all  imported. 

12  Wright,  op.  cit.,  p.  25. 

13  Figures  on  rainfall  and  arable  land  are  from  W.  S.  and  E.  S.  Woytinsky,  World 
Population  and  Production  (New  York,  1954),  p.  316.  For  somewhat  different  figures 
and  definitions  see  Trends  in  Economic  Growth,  Table  21,  p.  99,  based  on  the  Eco- 
nomic Bulletin  for  Europe,  Vol.  3,  No.  2  (1951),  pp.  22-23,  and  Yearbook  of  Food  and 
Agricultural  Statistics  (Washington,  1950),  Part  I,  pp.  13-17. 


1\     .    i 

I 
ll      ■ 

— *'*\' 

5  V  :'•'■• 

E  " 


i  0 

zoo 

4  00 

COO  Mi  | 

0 

200 

400           600  Km 

_„ 

._ 

Fig.    17-1.    Europe:    Railroads,    Resources,    and    Industrial    Concentrations    in    Western    Europe: 
(1)   industrial  regions;   (2)   coal;   (3)   lignite  coals;   (4)   iron  ore;  petroleum;   (6)   selected  rail- 
roads. 


540 


THE  ECONOMIC  CAPABILITIES  OF  WESTERN  EUROPE        541 

So  far  very  little  crude  oil  and  natural  gas  production  have  been  devel- 
oped in  Western  Europe.  The  poor  distribution  of  coal  and  the  absence  of 
petroleum  and  natural  gas  is  to  some  extent  compensated  by  substantial 
potential  and  actual  hydro-electrical  power  supplies  in  Italy,  France, 
Sweden,  Norway,  Switzerland,  and  Sweden. 

C.    The  Economic  Structure  of  Western  Europe 

GENERAL  CHARACTERISTICS 

The  group  of  countries  we  call  Western  Europe  covers  an  area  of 
1,784,000  square  miles  and  comprises  a  population  of  over  335  million 
people.  It  thus  includes  about  14  per  cent  of  the  population  of  the  globe 
but  only  about  3  per  cent  of  its  total  land  area.  It  has  an  average  popula- 
tion density  of  188  persons  per  square  mile  compared  with  45  for  the 
United  States,  21.5  for  Latin  America,  17  for  Africa,  and  123  for  Asia. 
After  the  United  States  and  Canada  it  is  the  most  highly  developed  area 
in  the  world  with  an  average  gross  national  product  per  capita  in  1955 
of  $891.  In  1948  the  combined  national  income  of  these  countries  was  esti- 
mated at  $122.6  billion  or  about  22  per  cent  of  the  world  total.14  Western 
Europe  in  1955  produced  527  million  tons  of  coal,  80  million  tons  of  steel, 
369  billion  kilowatt  hours  of  electricity,  and  547,000  tons  of  primary  alu- 
minum. These  production  figures  represented  the  following  percentages 
of  the  total  production  of  these  commodities  in  the  United  States,  Canada, 
and  Western  Europe  combined:  coal  53  per  cent,  steel  42  per  cent,  elec- 
tricity 34  per  cent,  and  aluminum  22  per  cent.  Western  Europe's  gross 
national  product  exceeds  that  of  the  entire  Communist  bloc;  on  a  per 
capita  basis  it  is  almost  four  times  as  great.  Western  European  steel  and 
electric  power  production  exceed  production  in  the  Communist  bloc. 
British,  Dutch,  and  French  companies  produce  at  home  and  overseas  more 
than  one  and  one-half  times  all  the  crude  oil  production  in  the  Commu- 
nist bloc.  Thus  the  community  of  Western  Europe  possesses  in  the  aggre- 
gate the  technological  and  resource  basis  for  great  power  status. 

The  economy  of  Western  Europe  as  a  whole  is  markedly  industrial, 
with  an  average  standard  of  living  below  that  of  the  United  States  but 
higher  than  that  of  any  other  important  region  in  the  world.  In  the  indus- 
trialized countries  of  Western  and  Central  Europe  a  high  standard  of  liv- 

14Woytinsky,  op.  cit.,  pp.  393,  394,  and  IR  7247,  Dept.  of  State  (Washington. 
D.  C,  1956). 


542       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

ing  results  from  the  use  of  specialized  capital  equipment  and  a  skilled 
labor  force  in  both  industry  and  agriculture.  The  basis  of  the  industrial 
life  of  Western  Europe  is  a  concentration  of  production  of  certain  key 
commodities,  especially  coal,  steel,  and  chemicals.  Using  its  own  produc- 
tion of  these  commodities,  plus  imports  of  other  necessary  raw  materials, 
Western  Europe  as  a  whole  produces  a  wide  range  of  manufactured 
goods,  both  for  producers  and  consumers,  a  relatively  large  part  of  which 
are  exported  to  pay  for  imports  of  raw  materials  and  foodstuffs. 

Western  Europe  is  primarily  industrial  also  in  the  sense  that  mining  and 
manufacturing  account  for  larger  shares  of  the  total  product  than  agricul- 
ture, fishing,  and  forestry  combined.  It  is  a  food-deficit  area:  in  1950-52 
imports  of  bread  grain  were  30  per  cent  of  consumption,  of  coarse  grains 
21  per  cent,  and  of  sugar  36  per  cent.15  In  terms  of  calories,  Western 
Europe  depends  on  imports  for  about  one-fifth  of  its  food  supplies.  How- 
ever, it  must  not  be  assumed  that  agriculture  is  of  no  importance.  The 
bulk  of  Western  Europe's  food  requirements  are  supplied  from  within  the 
area,  and  the  proportion  of  active  workers  engaged  in  agriculture  ranges 
from  about  one-fifth  in  northwestern  Europe  to  about  one-half  in  southern 
Europe.16  The  share  of  agriculture  in  national  income  ranges  from  be- 
tween 5  and  10  per  cent  for  the  United  Kingdom  and  Belgium  to  between 
30  and  40  per  cent  for  Ireland,  Iceland,  and  Greece.17 

ENERGY  AND  FUEL  SUPPLY 

The  industrialized  countries  of  western  and  northern  Europe  are  high 
energy  consuming  countries,  particularly  the  United  Kingdom,  Germany, 
Belgium,  Norway,  and  Sweden.18  Coal  is  still  the  dominant  source  of 
energy,  accounting  in  1950  for  about  four-fifths  of  the  total  energy  sup- 
ply.19 

In  some  countries  (Norway,  Finland,  Sweden,  Italy,  Austria,  and 
Switzerland)  three-quarters  or  more  of  total  electricity  supplies  come 
from  hydro-electric  plants,  but  these  countries  were  either  small  or  their 
total  energy  consumption  low  relative  to  the  larger,  more  industrialized 

15  Economic  Commission  for  Europe  (ECE),  Economic  Survey  of  Europe  Since 
the  War  (Geneva,  1954),  p.  170. 

16  Economic  Commission  for  Europe,  Growth  and  Stagnation  in  the  European 
Economy  (Geneva,  1954),  Table  A.  4..  p.  237. 

17  Trends  in  Economic  Groicth,  A  Comparison  of  the  Western  Powers  and  the 
Soviet  Bloc,  Legislative  Reference  Service  (Washington,  1955),  pp.  272,  273. 

18  Point  Four,  Department  of  State  Publication  3719,  January,  1950,  Appendix  C-4, 
p.  119. 

19  ECE,  Growth  and  Stagnation,  etc.,  p.  104. 


THE  ECONOMIC  CAPABILITIES  OF  WESTERN  EUROPE        543 

countries,  so  that  for  Western  Europe  as  a  whole  water  power  accounted 
for  only  12  per  cent  of  total  commercial  energy.20 

Petroleum  products  and  natural  gas  supply  about  10  per  cent  of  West- 
ern Europe's  energy  requirements,  but  petroleum  production  is  small, 
amounting  in  1953  to  only  3.6  million  metric  tons,  almost  entirely  in  West- 
ern Germany  and  France.  The  resulting  deficit  is  made  up  by  imports  of 
crude  petroleum  and  petroleum  products. 

Assuring  an  adequate  and  expanding  supply  of  energy  in  the  light  of 
coal  production  difficulties  and  the  failure  to  find  oil  in  significant  quanti- 
ties on  the  continent  has  become  one  of  Western  Europe's  chief  economic 
(and  strategic)  problems.  See  below  (page  559)  for  further  discussion  of 
this  problem. 

INDUSTRY  AND  MANUFACTURING 

The  iron  and  steel  industry  is  the  industrial  core  of  Western  Europe. 
The  output  of  the  iron  and  steel  industry  is  sufficient  to  provide  for  the 
needs  of  the  region  and  to  supply  about  three-fourths  of  the  Free  World's 
exports  of  steel  products  to  overseas  markets.  Steel  production  in  Western 
Europe  is  concentrated  in  four  major  producing  areas,  the  United  King- 
dom, Western  Germany,  France  and  the  Saar,  and  Belgium-Luxembourg 
( cf.  Fig.  17-1,  p.  540 ) .  While  the  United  Kingdom  has  the  largest  produc- 
tion, France  and  Belgium-Luxembourg  are  the  largest  exporters,  selling 
more  than  50  per  cent  of  their  production  abroad. 

The  big  continental  coal  and  steel-producing  areas  are  interdependent. 
Western  Germany,  the  largest  coal  and  steel  producer,  exports  coking  coal 
and  coke  and  imports  more  than  half  of  its  iron  ore  requirements.  France 
is  a  net  exporter  of  iron  ore  and  imports  coal  and  coke.  Belgium-Luxem- 
bourg exports  steel  in  large  quantities  but  must  import  both  iron  ore  and 
coke. 

This  heavy  industrial  base  exists  to  support  a  wide  range  of  both  heavy 
and  light  manufacturing.  For  the  countries  of  north  and  west  Europe 
manufacturing  accounts  for  between  25  per  cent  and  35  per  cent  of  na- 
tional income.  For  Italy  also  the  proportion  is  about  30  per  cent;  for  the 
other  countries  of  southern  Europe  the  ratio  is  considerably  less  ( as  20  per 
cent  for  Greece).21  The  most  important  manufacturing  activities  in  West- 
ern Europe  are  the  engineering  (machinery),  textiles,  and  chemicals  in- 
dustries. These  industries  account  for  the  largest  share  of  the  national 

20  See  Trends  in  Economic  Growth,  p.  151. 

21  Trends  in  Economic  Growth,  Table  3, 


544       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

product  and  employment  and  are  most  important  to  the  strategic  mobili- 
zation of  economic  capabilities. 

Output  of  engineering  products  (machinery,  electrical  goods,  vehicles 
and  transportation  equipment)  in  Western  Europe  in  1951  amounted  to 
$18  billion  or  roughly  10  per  cent  of  the  gross  national  product.  Of  this 
output  about  $3.3  billion  was  exported,  leaving  $14.7  billion  for  use  in 
Western  Europe.22  The  United  Kingdom  and  West  Germany  are,  of 
course,  the  big  producers  of  engineering  products. 

The  automobile  industry  is  an  important  sector  in  the  engineering  cate- 
gory. Motor  vehicle  production  in  1950  was  1.6  million  vehicles.  In  the 
interwar  period  the  shipyards  of  Western  Europe  produced  80  per  cent 
of  the  world's  new  merchant  vessels,  but  in  1950  the  share  had  fallen  to 
46  per  cent. 

The  textiles  industry  is  almost  as  important  as  the  machinery  industry 
although  perhaps  of  less  strategic  importance.  The  textiles  industry  ac- 
counts (1950-51)  for  8  per  cent  of  all  manufacturing  employment  in  Nor- 
way and  Sweden,  11  to  12  per  cent  in  the  United  Kingdom,  Denmark,  and 
the  Netherlands,  and  18  to  19  per  cent  in  Italy  and  Belgium.  Exports  of 
textiles,  especially  of  cotton  textiles,  are  still  Western  Europe's  principal 
export. 

The  chemical  industry  is  another  European  industry  which  is  of  first 
importance  both  economically  and  strategically.  The  chemical  industry 
was  developed  in  Europe  in  the  nineteenth  century  and  at  the  time  of 
World  War  I  Western  Europe  accounted  for  over  50  per  cent  of  world 
production  and  over  80  per  cent  of  world  exports  of  chemicals,23  to  a 
large  extent  because  of  German  leadership  in  synthetic  dyestuffs  and 
pharmaceutical  chemicals.  Subsequently,  Western  Europe's  share  of  world 
chemical  production  declined  because  of  the  expansion  of  the  chemicals 
industry  in  the  United  States  and  the  U.S.S.R.  However,  exports  of  chemi- 
cal products  have  retained  their  percentage  share  of  total  Western  Euro- 
pean exports.24 

TRANSPORTATION 

The  countries  of  central  and  northwestern  Europe  (France,  Belgium, 
Netherlands,  Germany,  Austria)  and  the  United  Kingdom  have  extensive 
inland  water  transportation  systems.  The  United  Kingdom  has  4,600  miles 
of  navigable  waterway  with  an  ingenious  network  of  interlocking  canals 

22  Trends  in  Economic  Growth,  Table  3. 

23  ECE,  Growth  and  Stagnation,  pp.  163-165. 

24  Ibid. 


THE  ECONOMIC  CAPABILITIES  OF  WESTERN  EUROPE        545 

constructed  mostly  in  the  pre-railway  early  nineteenth  century.  In  1954, 
the  canals  of  the  Docks  and  Inland  Waterways  Board  (excluding  the 
Manchester  Ship  Canal)  carried  only  about  ISO  million  short  ton  miles. 
France  has  almost  6,000  miles  of  navigable  waterways  connecting  the 
waterways  systems  of  the  Seine,  the  Rhine,  and  the  Rhone.  About  11,000 
craft  carried  more  than  5  billion  short  ton  miles  in  1954. 

There  are  about  3,000  miles  of  navigable  waterways  in  West  Germany, 
including  the  Rhine  which  is  the  backbone  of  the  system.  In  1954  West 
Germany  had  an  inland  fleet  of  more  than  7,000  craft  carrying  about  8.5 
billion  short  ton  miles  of  freight.25 

The  Rhine  flows  through  Europe's  greatest  industrial  concentrations, 
carrying  coal,  coke  and  grain  upstream,  and  timber,  potash  and  iron  ore 
downstream.  It  is  primarily  a  German  river,  and  most  of  the  industries 
served  by  it  and  most  of  the  traffic  along  its  course  are  German.  Yet  in  its 
delta  regions  the  Rhine  is  controlled  by  the  Netherlands  and  by  Belgium. 
A  net  of  inland  canals  constructed  by  Germany,  Belgium,  and  the  Nether- 
lands bears  witness  to  the  competing  interests  of  the  three  nations,  with 
Germany  striving,  through  means  of  port  diversion,  to  gain  an  outlet  to 
the  sea  which  is  not  controlled  by  other  states,  and  the  Low  Countries 
(Belgium,  of  course,  is  not  directly  on  the  Rhine)  intent  on  channelling 
as  much  Rhine  traffic  as  possible  toward  their  ports.  Of  the  German  efforts 
directed  at  port  diversion  the  Dortmund-Ems  canal  extension  to  Emden, 
and  the  Mittelland  Canal,  linking  the  Ruhr  with  the  Elbe  River,  Berlin, 
and  the  Oder  River  are  the  most  important.  The  operation  of  this  net  work, 
however,  has  been  hampered  by  the  East-West  division  of  the  country 
since  the  Midland  system  is  in  the  East  Zone.  This  had  led  to  controversies 
between  the  occupying  powers,  especially  in  connection  with  the  use  of 
the  canals  in  and  around  Berlin.26 

Upstream,  Switzerland  and  Austria  share  a  vital  interest  in  participation 
in  Rhine  river  traffic.  Both  of  them  are  landlocked.  Whereas  the  Rhine 
river  basin  with  the  now  very  important  port  of  Basel  represents  the 
natural  outlet  to  the  sea  for  Switzerland,  Austria  is  oriented  toward  the 
Danube.  A  linking  of  the  basins  of  the  Rhine  and  the  Danube  would  be 
of  major  importance  since  a  completed  and  internationally  functioning 
Rhine-Main-Danube  canal  would  open  up  a  new  inland  canal  avenue 
from  the  North  Sea  to  the  Mediterranean  via  the  Black  Sea.  However,  thus 
far  only  the  Main  up  to  Wiirzburg  has  been  fully  canalized  and  the  pros- 
pect for  completion  of  the  whole  work  before  1970  appears  slim  at  the 

25  Economic  Commission  for  Europe,  Annual  Bulletin  of  Statistics,  1954. 

26  See  G.  Hoffman,  ed.,  A  Geography  of  Europe  (New  York,  1953),  pp.  410-411. 


546       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

present  time.  Not  only  is  the  Danube  at  times  beset  by  navigational  diffi- 
culties, but  the  political  odds  created  by  the  control  of  the  lower  Danube 
by  the  U.S.S.R.  and  the  satellite  nations  of  Moscow  still  seem  to  militate 
against  the  kind  of  international  co-operation  which  had  been  carried  out 
by  the  European  Danube  Commission  on  the  maritime  Danube  (Braila- 
Black  Sea)  since  1856  and  by  the  International  Danube  Commission  on 
the  fluvial  Danube  (Ulm-Braila)  after  World  War  I.  On  the  basis  of  the 
U.S.S.R.-inspired  Belgrade  Convention  of  1948,  the  Soviet-Satellite- Yugo- 
slav stretch  of  the  Danube  has  been  controlled  by  the  Budapest  (former 
Galati)  Danube  Commission  since  1949,  while  traffic  between  Germany 
and  Austria  on  the  one  hand  and  the  lower  Danube  nations  on  the  other 
moves  on  the  basis  of  bilateral  agreements. 

As  other  major  projects  for  the  future  may  be  mentioned  that  of  the 
canalization  of  the  upper  Rhine  between  the  Lake  of  Constance  and  Basel 
and  that  of  a  Rhine-Rhone  waterway  which  would  provide  Switzerland 
with  two  links  to  the  open  sea  and  France  with  an  important  new  route 
to  North  Africa. 

Despite  the  extensive  ramification  of  navigable  waterways  in  north- 
west Europe,  the  inland  waterways  of  Western  Europe,  according  to  sta- 
tistics of  the  Economic  Commission  for  Europe,  carry  only  about  one-fifth 
of  all  the  water  and  rail  freight  (ton  miles)  moved  in  Western  Europe.27 
This  is  about  the  same  proportion  as  obtained  before  World  War  II 
(1938).  In  the  postwar  period  the  importance  of  road  transport  has  in- 
creased at  the  expense  of  rail  transport  but  the  latter  remains  the  most 
important  single  method  of  internal  transport  for  Western  Europe  as  a 
whole.  Motor  transport  in  the  interwar  period  did  not  increase  as  it  did  in 
the  United  States  partly  because  motor-vehicle  production  was  not  so 
advanced,  partly  because  of  state  regulations  intended  to  protect  the  rail- 
ways from  motor-vehicle  competition.  However,  road  transport  has  made 
considerable  progress  in  the  United  Kingdom,  France,  Germany,  and  Italy. 

Railroads  (cf.  Fig.  17-1,  p.  540)  still  transport  the  great  bulk  of  do- 
mestic and  particularly  of  international  freight  and  passenger  traffic  in 
Europe.  A  certain  amount  of  international  integration  already  had  been 
achieved  in  the  nineteenth  century.  It  comprised  agreements  on  the 
( standard )  gauge  to  be  used  on  all  principal  railways  between  the  borders 
of  Spain  and  Russia,  on  the  characteristics  of  railway  cars  and  on  the 
international  transport  contract.  These  agreements  also  extended  to  time 
tables  for  international  freight  and  passenger  trains  which  to  a  certain 
extent  provided  the  framework  into  which  the  national  train  schedules  had 

27  Economic  Commission  for  Europe,  Annual  Bulletin  of  Transport  Statistics,  1954. 


THE  ECONOMIC  CAPABILITIES  OF  WESTERN  EUROPE        547 

to  fit.  Most  of  these  conventions  are  administered  by  international  agen- 
cies, partly  governmental  but  largely  inter-carrier  organizations  which, 
however,  due  to  the  nationalization  of  practically  all  principal  railroads, 
have  quasi-governmental  character.  In  spite  of  the  political  division  of 
Europe  with  the  appearance  of  the  Iron  Curtain  nearly  all  of  these  con- 
ventions and  arrangements  are  still  in  force  and  the  international  organi- 
zations, such  as  those  for  car  exchanges,  time  tables,  the  international 
transport  contract,  and  the  handling  of  dangerous  goods,  continue  to 
operate  on  both  sides  of  the  Iron  Curtain  (excepting  in  most  instances, 
however,  as  was  the  case  before  World  War  II,  the  Soviet  Union). 

Closer  integration  of  Western  European  railways  is  being  attempted 
now,  mainly  under  the  aegis  of  such  post-World  War  II  organizations  as 
the  European  Coal  and  Steel  Community,  the  European  Conference  of 
Ministers  of  Transport,  and  the  Council  of  Europe.  The  West  European 
countries  already  have  pooled  about  10  per  cent  of  their  freight  cars,  they 
are  about  to  centralize  their  car  and  perhaps  also  locomotive  purchases, 
and  the  most  important  rail  tariffs  of  the  Coal  and  Steel  Community  coun- 
tries are  in  the  process  of  being  integrated. 

AGRICULTURE 

The  relative  economic  importance  of  agriculture  differs  widely  within 
the  region,  and  the  same  is  true  of  the  character  of  agriculture  in  the  dif- 
ferent countries,  corresponding  to  differences  in  climate,  soil,  density  of 
agricultural  population,  size  of  land  holdings,  and  agricultural  techniques. 
"Within  the  area,  most  farming  systems,  apart  from  the  purely  tropical, 
would  be  found:  from  the  rough  grazings  of  the  upland  districts  of  Scan- 
dinavia and  the  northern  parts  of  the  United  Kingdom  to  the  vineyards  of 
southern  France  and  Italy  and  the  tobacco  fields  of  Greece.  While  single 
crops  were  often  important,  in  general  mixed  farming  predominated  over 
monoculture.  Farming  was  intensive  and  crop  yields  were  well  above 
those  of  the  rest  of  the  world."  2S 

The  principal  crops  are  wheat,  barley,  corn,  potatoes,  sugar  beets,  meat 
and  dairy  products,  wine,  and  citrus  fruits.  Some  cotton  and  tobacco  are 
grown.  Crop  yields  for  wheat  and  barley  are  about  the  same  in  Southern 
Europe  (Greece,  Italy,  Portugal,  and  Turkey)  as  in  the  United  States  but 
are  considerably  higher  in  the  other  OEEC  countries.  Crop  yields  for  corn 

are  from  two-thirds  to  five-sixths  of  the  United  States  average.  The  de- 

o 

28  Committee  of  European  Co-operation,  Technical  Report,  Vol.  2  (Paris,  1947), 
p.  21. 


548        THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

gree  of  mechanization  ( number  of  tractors  per  acre  of  agricultural  land ) 
in  some  countries,  notably  the  United  Kingdom,  Switzerland,  Sweden, 
Norway,  West  Germany,  and  Denmark,  compares  not  unfavorably  with 
that  of  the  United  States.  The  use  of  chemical  fertilizers  is  well-advanced 
in  northwestern  Europe  and  is  increasing  in  southern  Europe. 

Nearly  all  the  countries  are  substantial  importers  of  bread  grains,  al- 
though France  and  Spain  are  nearly  self-sufficient  and  Turkey  usually  a 
net  exporter.  The  same  is  true  of  coarse  grains,  except  that  Denmark  and 
Finland  are  virtually  self-sufficient  while  the  countries  of  southern  Europe 
are  either  self-sufficient  or  net  exporters.  France  and  Denmark  export 
sugar  and  the  Netherlands  and  Denmark  are  heavy  exporters  of  dairy 
products.  Denmark,  Ireland,  and  the  Netherlands  export  meat  and  meat 
produce  and  livestock  (Ireland),  and  import  vegetable  products,  partly 
for  the  feeding  of  livestock.  Some  of  the  problems  involved  in  increasing 
agricultural  production  in  Western  Europe  are  discussed  below  (see 
pp.  549,  560-561). 

REGIONAL  PATTERNS 

The  bulk  of  Western  Europe's  population  is  concentrated  in  seven 
countries  which  account  for  roughly  three-fifths  of  the  population  but  less 
than  a  third  of  the  total  area.  These  are  the  United  Kingdom,  France 
(with  the  Saar),  West  Germany,  Italy,  Belgium-Luxembourg,  and  the 
Netherlands.  These  seven  states  are  the  core  of  Western  Europe's  eco- 
nomic and  industrial  capabilities. 

These  are  not  the  most  prosperous  countries  in  Western  Europe.  In  fact, 
five  other  countries  (Norway,  Denmark,  Iceland,  Sweden,  and  Switzer- 
land) have  per  capita  gross  national  products  as  high  as  or  higher  than 
that  of  the  United  Kingdom,  which  is  the  wealthiest  of  the  seven  states 
mentioned  above.  But  these  five  countries  account  for  only  20  million 
people  and  their  aggregate  gross  product  came  in  1952-53  to  about  $20 
billion.  The  larger  group  of  states  referred  to  above  had  a  combined  gross 
product  of  $143.6  billion,  or  three-fourths  of  the  value  of  all  goods  and 
services  produced  in  the  whole  of  the  region  we  call  Western  Europe.  If 
the  two  groups  of  states  are  combined  they  represent  about  70  per  cent 
of  the  population  and  85  per  cent  of  the  production. 

If  we  look  to  measures  of  industrial  power  such  as  steel  and  coal  pro- 
duction, the  larger  group  of  seven  states  is  even  more  clearly  apparent  as 
the  core  area  of  Western  Europe.  Here  is  produced  90  per  cent  of  all  the 
crude  steel,  95  per  cent  of  the  coal,  and  70  per  cent  of  the  electric  power 


THE  ECONOMIC  CAPABILITIES  OF  WESTERN  EUROPE        549 

for  Western  Europe  as  a  whole.  The  railroads  of  these  countries  carry  more 
than  three-fourths  of  the  total  ton  kilometers  of  freight  transported  by  rail 
in  all  of  Western  Europe.  Of  the  other  countries  only  Sweden  can  really 
pretend  to  being  an  industrial  power  with  a  gross  national  product  of 
over  $8  billion  in  1952-53  ( greater  than  either  Belgium  or  Holland ) ,  crude 
steel  production  of  1.8  million  metric  tons  ( Holland  had  less  than  1  mil- 
lion metric  tons ) ,  and  electric  power  production  more  than  twice  as  great 
as  Belgium's  and  three  times  as  great  as  Holland's.  However,  it  must  be 
noted  that  Sweden,  because  of  its  traditional  neutrality,  lies  outside  the 
framework  of  European  defense  arrangements. 

The  countries  in  which  the  agricultural  sectors  are  most  highly  devel- 
oped and  production  most  efficient  are  likewise  the  United  Kingdom  and 
the  countries  of  northern  and  western  Europe.  With  only  24  per  cent  of 
the  active  population  in  agriculture  and  28  per  cent  of  the  arable  land 
they  produce  almost  half  of  the  agricultural  products  in  all  of  Western 
Europe.  The  countries  of  southern  Europe  ( Greece,  Italy,  Portugal,  Spain, 
Turkey,  and  Yugoslavia)  on  the  other  hand,  with  more  than  two-thirds 
of  the  active  population  in  agriculture  and  over  one-half  of  the  arable 
land  account  for  only  one-third  of  the  agricultural  output.29  Thus  yields 
are  considerably  lower  in  southern  Europe  and  productivity  per  worker 
even  less  than  in  north  and  west  Europe. 

Agriculture  in  the  United  Kingdom  is  the  most  efficient  in  all  of  West- 
ern Europe.  This  is  partly  because  of  the  early  elimination  of  small  hold- 
ings and  the  consequent  low  density  of  agricultural  population,  the  lack 
of  tariff  protection  during  the  last  half  of  the  nineteenth  century  and  the 
early  decades  of  the  twentieth,  and  the  wartime  and  postwar  efforts  to 
increase  output  for  the  purpose  of  economizing  foreign  exchange.  Agri- 
cultural output  in  the  Scandinavian  countries  is  also  relatively  high  both 
per  hectare  and  per  worker.30 

FOREIGN  TRADE 

In  the  countries  of  Western  Europe  the  principle  of  international  divi- 
sion of  labor  is  carried  farther  than  in  any  other  important  region.  In  other 
words,  with  a  heavy  specialization  in  manufacturing  and  a  concomitant 
dependence  upon  imported  supplies  of  foodstuffs  and  raw  materials,  for- 
eign trade  is  critically  important  to  Western  Europe.  Roughly  10  per  cent 
of  the  national  income  represents  goods  exported  to  pay  for  imports,  as 

29  ECE,  Economic  Survey  of  Europe  Since  the  War,  p.  164. 

30  Ibid.,  165. 


550       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

contrasted  with  only  4  per  cent  in  the  United  States  and  1  per  cent  for 
the  U.S.S.R.  Western  Europe's  imports  from  the  rest  of  the  world  consist 
mainly  of  raw  materials  for  Europe's  manufacturing  industries  (51  per 
cent),  foodstuffs  and  animal  feed  (34  per  cent),  and  some  manufactured 
products  ( 15  per  cent ) ;  exports  to  the  rest  of  the  world  are  mainly  manu- 
factured goods  (74  per  cent)  with  some  raw  materials  (16  per  cent)  and 
foodstuffs  (10  per  cent).31 

This  high  degree  of  reliance  on  foreign  trade  has  been  one  of  the  condi- 
tions of  economic  progress  for  Western  Europe,  but  it  also  has  other  im- 
portant consequences,  both  economic  and  strategic.  It  not  only  makes  the 
area  vulnerable  to  disruption  of  shipping  in  time  of  war;  it  also  subjects 
the  economy  to  the  shock  of  economic  changes  in  the  rest  of  the  world, 
such  as  changes  in  the  degree  and  character  of  demand  for  manufactured 
goods,  or  higher  prices  for  raw  materials  and  foodstuffs.  Europe's  pros- 
perity and  stability  depend  therefore  not  only  on  the  efforts  of  Europeans 
but  as  well  on  the  maintenance  of  full  employment  in  the  United  States, 
and  on  a  continuous  expansion  of  supplies  of  raw  materials  and  foodstuffs 
in  overseas  areas.  The  degree  of  this  dependence  is  greater  for  some  coun- 
tries than  others;  in  Holland,  for  example,  35  per  cent  of  the  gross  national 
product  is  based  on  foreign  trade. 

Reference  has  already  been  made  to  Europe's  dependence  on  imported 
food  and  feeding  stuffs.  Western  Europe  is  also  the  world's  largest  im- 
porter of  raw  cotton  and  raw  wool.  Other  raw  materials  imported  in  large 
quantities  include  rubber,  jute,  non-ferrous  metals  (copper  and  lead), 
sulphur,  and  crude  petroleum. 

Traditionally,  Western  Europe  has  had  an  adverse  trade  balance,  that 
is,  its  exports  paid  for  only  about  two-thirds  of  its  imports  from  the  rest  of 
the  world;  and  the  deficit  was  offset  by  a  surplus  on  "invisible"  transac- 
tions, that  is,  income  from  shipping,  insurance,  and  overseas  investments. 
Now,  however,  as  a  result  of  the  reduction  in  overseas  investments  during 
the  war,  increased  indebtedness,  and  the  larger  role  of  United  States  ship- 
ping in  ocean  transportation,  Western  Europe's  surplus  on  "invisibles" 
pays  for  a  much  smaller  proportion  of  its  total  imports.  This  fact,  plus  the 
need  to  obtain  a  larger  share  of  total  imports  from  the  dollar  currency  area 
in  the  postwar  period,  and  other  and  more  complicated  factors,  created 
the  European  balance-of-payments  problem  and  its  acuter  manifestation 
known  as  the  dollar  shortage  or  dollar  gap.  More  will  be  said  about  this  in 
a  later  section. 

31  Organization  for  European  Economic  Co-operation  (OEEC),  At  Work  for 
Europe  (Paris,  1954),  p.  14;  percentages  are  for  OEEC  countries  in  1952, 


THE  ECONOMIC  CAPABILITIES  OF  WESTERN  EUROPE        551 

Although  the  dollar  problem  in  Western  Europe's  balance-of-payments 
should  not  be  minimized,  it  should  be  noted  that  trade  with  the  dollar 
area  is  by  no  means  the  bulk  of  Europe's  trade.  In  1953,  imports  from  the 
dollar  area  were  about  15  per  cent  of  the  total  imports,  and  exports  to  the 
dollar  area  about  12  per  cent  of  total  exports,  if  intra-European  trade  is 
included  in  the  total.  Intra-European  trade  is  nearly  half  of  the  total  for- 
eign trade  of  Western  European  countries.32  However,  as  pointed  out  in 
another  chapter,  trade  with  Eastern  Europe  has  been  very  sharply  re- 
duced.33 Another  large  share  (13  per  cent  in  1953)  of  Europe's  trade 
is  with  the  overseas  territories  of  the  United  Kingdom,  France,  Belgium, 
Portugal,  and  the  Netherlands.  These  territories,  such  as  the  British  West 
Indies,  Malaya,  Singapore  and  Hong-Kong,  British  Africa,  the  French 
possessions  in  Africa  and  Oceania,  the  Belgian  Congo,  and  others,34  are 
linked  to  the  metropolitan  areas  by  a  network  of  administrative  and  finan- 
cial ties.  The  overseas  territories  constitute  a  common  currency  area  with 
the  mother  country  ( the  franc  area,  the  Belgian  monetary  area,  etc. ) ,  and 
tariff  arrangements  and  import  restrictions  on  both  sides  discriminate  in 
favor  of  trade  between  the  possession  and  the  metropole.  Thus  in  1953, 
the  share  of  the  metropolitan  country  in  the  imports  of  the  territories 
ranged  from  30  per  cent  in  the  British  territories  to  65  per  cent  in  the 
French,  while  one-third  of  the  exports  of  the  British  and  Portuguese  terri- 
tories, two-thirds  of  the  French  territories'  exports,  and  over  half  ( includ- 
ing re-exports)  of  the  Belgian  Congo's  exports  went  to  the  metropolitan 
countries. 

The  British  monetary  area,  called  the  sterling  area  for  a  variety  of 
reasons  goes  beyond  the  British  overseas  territories  and  includes  a  num- 
ber of  independent  countries.  In  the  main  these  are  members  of  the  British 
Commonwealth,  such  as  Australia  and  New  Zealand,  the  Union  of  South 
Africa,  India  and  Ceylon,  but  there  are  examples  also  of  non-common- 
wealth sterling  countries  in  Iceland  and  Iraq.  Since  the  gold  and  dollar 
reserves  of  the  sterling  area  are  largely  held  in  London,  it  is  necessary  for 
members  as  far  as  possible  to  follow  concerted  trade  and  exchange  poli- 
cies. Co-ordination  of  these  policies  takes  place  usually  through  periodic 
meetings  of  the  finance  ministers  and  central  banking  authorities  of  the 
commonwealth  countries. 

32  OEEC,  Sixth  Report,  Vol.  1,  p.  252. 

33  See  above,  p.  493. 

34  OEEC,  op.  cit.,  pp.  245-7,  contains  a  convenient  list  of  these  territories.  The 
relative  size  and  importance  of  the  overseas  territories  is  to  some  extent  indicated  b\ 
the  following  population  figures  (in  millions):  British  territories,  74;  French,  53; 
Belgian,  16;  Portuguese,  11;  Netherlands,  1.5;  Italian  Trust  Territory,   1. 


552       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

D.    Dynamic  Factors  in  the  Western  European  Economy 

In  the  foregoing  sections  of  this  chapter  we  have  seen  how,  in  the  nine- 
teenth century,  the  expansion  and  industrialization  of  the  European  econ- 
omy was  correlated  with  the  great  period  of  European  imperialism  from 
1870  to  1910,  while  in  the  twentieth  century,  after  two  world  wars,  Eu- 
rope's economic  pre-eminence  was  superseded,  and  its  empire  began  to 
disintegrate.  To  cast  some  light  upon  the  relation  between  political  power 
and  economic  capabilities  we  proceeded  to  look  briefly  at  the  economic 
geography  of  Europe  and  the  main  outlines  of  the  structure  of  the  Euro- 
pean economy.  It  is  now  in  order  to  complete  our  examination  of  these 
problems  by  inquiring  into  the  factors  affecting  the  long-range  growth  of 
the  European  economy  and  its  future  prospects. 


PRESENT  POSITION  OF  EUROPE  IN  THE 
WORLD  ECONOMY 

No  one  questioned  the  industrial  pre-eminence  of  Western  Europe  in 
the  decade  before  the  first  World  War.  In  1913  Western  Europe  probably 
accounted  for  about  one-half  of  the  world's  manufacturing  output.  The 
preceding  several  decades  had  been  a  period  of  rapid  industrial  expan- 
sion. Industrial  production  had  been  growing  by  about  3  per  cent  per  year 
and  about  2  per  cent  per  capita  annually.35  There  was  unbounded  confi- 
dence that  the  next  several  decades  would  witness  more  of  the  same. 
However,  by  1937,  Western  Europe's  share  of  total  world  'manufacturing 
output  was  reduced  to  little  more  than  one-third,  and  by  1954  it  had 
shrunk  to  between  one-third  and  one-fourth.36 

This  decline  in  Western  Europe's  importance  was  a  relative  one,  for 
Western  Europe's  economies  continued  to  grow  after  1913  but  at  a  slower 
rate.  Between  1913  and  1940  industrial  output  grew  by  only  about  1.4  per 
cent  per  year  and  0.8  per  cent  per  year  per  capita.37  The  United  States, 
on  the  other  hand,  whose  rate  of  growth  even  before  1913  had  been  more 
rapid  than  that  of  Western  Europe,  caught  up  during  the  first  World  War 
and  pulled  ahead  during  the  second,  while  the  U.S.S.R.  experienced  a 
greatly  accelerated  rate  of  growth  after  1920.  Today  its  industrial  power 
is  approaching  that  of  all  Western  European  countries  combined. 

The  present  and  prospective  relative  position  of  Western  Europe  in  the 

35  ECE,  Growth  and  Stagnation  in  the  European  Economy,  p.  56. 

36  Department  of  State,  Long-term  Trends  Affecting  Western  Europe's  Position 
in  the  World  Economy,  IR  No.  6929  (Washington,  1955). 

3  7  Ibid. 


THE  ECONOMIC  CAPABILITIES  OF  WESTERN  EUROPE        553 

world  economy  is  not  merely  a  question  of  the  over-all  rate  of  growth; 
it  also  involves  the  question  of  the  growth  of  the  relatively  underdevel- 
oped regions  of  southern  Europe:  Greece,  Turkey,  Southern  Italy,  Spain, 
and  Portugal.  Industrialization  in  Western  Europe  did  not  occur  uni- 
formly and  even  in  1913,  when  Western  Europe's  relative  importance  was 
greatest,  industry  was  concentrated  in  a  few  countries  in  the  north  and 
west.  The  three  great  powers,  the  United  Kingdom,  Germany,  and  France, 
accounted  for  more  than  three-fourths  of  industrial  output  although  they 
held  only  46  per  cent  of  the  population.  Their  production  was  ori- 
ented toward  export  markets  and  was  heavily  weighted  with  capital 
goods.38  Agriculture  still  occupied  more  than  two-fifths  of  Europe's  popu- 
lation, and  the  proportion  was  much  higher  in  the  countries  of  southern 
Europe. 

This  uneven  pattern  of  economic  development  was  in  part  the  reflection 
of  the  uneven  geographical  distribution  of  resources,  especially  coal  and 
iron  ore;  in  part  it  was  the  result  of  more  complex  social  and  political  in- 
fluences. An  understanding  of  these  is  essential  to  the  understanding  of 
Western  Europe's  prospects,  which  depend  not  only  on  the  continuation 
of  the  present  pattern  and  rates  of  growth  but  also  on  the  modernization 
of  the  less-developed  regions. 

In  analyzing  the  dynamic  factors  in  Western  Europe's  economic  posi- 
tion we  will  find  it  convenient  to  group  them  under  two  headings,  internal 
factors  and  external  factors.  However,  there  are  considerations  that  can- 
not neatly  be  ranked  under  either  heading,  especially  the  effect  of  the  two 
great  wars  that  were  fought  on  European  soil. 

INTERNAL  FACTORS:   MANPOWER  AND  PRODUCTIVITY 

Internal  factors  affecting  the  growth  of  Europe's  economic  capabilities 
are  the  size  of  the  labor  force,  its  distribution  among  employments  of  dif- 
ferent productivities,  and  the  rate  at  which  the  average  productivity  of 
the  labor  force  increases,  which  in  turn  depends  on  technology,  invest- 
ment, and  on  other  factors.  Western  Europe's  population  increased  by 
about  7  per  cent  between  1938  and  1952  compared  with  a  20  per  cent 
increase  in  the  United  States  and  approximately  the  same  increase  for  the 
population  within  the  present  boundaries  of  the  U.S.S.R.  And  whereas 
the  annual  increase  in  population  for  both  the  United  States  and  the 
U.S.S.R.  is  estimated  at  around  1.7  per  cent,  it  is  slightly  less  than  1  per 
cent  for  Western  Europe.  Western  Europe's  labor  force  increased  by 

38  ECE,  Growth  and  Stagnation  in  the  European  Economy,  p.  16. 


554       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

about  10  per  cent  between  1938  and  1948,  and  at  the  end  of  1953  was 
about  125  million.  It  was  thus  almost  twice  as  large  as  that  of  the  United 
States,  although  the  total  value  of  gross  production  was  only  a  little  more 
than  one-half  as  great.  The  European  and  United  States  labor  forces  are 
expected  to  grow  at  about  the  same  rate  for  the  next  fifteen  years,  reach- 
ing about  200  million  for  Western  Europe  and  103  million  for  the  United 
States  by  1970. 39  Both  populations  will  show  increasing  "aging."  The  larg- 
est and  economically  most  important  states,  France,  Belgium,  Germany, 
and  the  United  Kingdom  will  not  grow  as  fast  as  Western  Europe  as  a 
whole.  This  points  to  one  of  Europe's  unsolved  problems  of  adjustment- 
how  to  transfer  workers  from  faster-growing  populations  in  the  less-devel- 
oped countries  to  nonagricultural  employment  in  the  more  industrialized 
regions. 

In  the  OEEC  countries  about  30  per  cent  of  the  labor  force  is  employed 
in  agriculture.40  The  proportion  of  the  active  population  in  manufacturing 
industry  has  increased  over  the  last  two  decades  while  the  active  popula- 
tion in  agriculture  has  declined.  However,  there  are  marked  differences 
between  different  countries  in  the  recent  patterns  of  changes  in  man- 
power and  employment.  For  example  in  the  United  Kingdom  the  popula- 
tion of  working  ages  had  by  1952  increased  by  10  per  cent  over  1930,  but 
employment  in  manufacturing,  construction,  transport,  and  other  services 
increased  by  between  10  and  20  per  cent.  The  offsetting  declines  in  agri- 
culture and  mining  were  not  enough  to  prevent  a  severe  labor  shortage. 
In  France,  on  the  other  hand,  alone  of  all  the  countries  in  Western  Europe, 
employment  in  manufacturing  was  lower  in  1951  than  twenty  years  ear- 
lier, as  was  also  employment  in  mining,  construction,  and  transport.  Em- 
ployment in  trade  and  services,  however,  had  increased,  with  a  conse- 
quent reduction  in  the  average  output  in  these  occupations. 

The  tendency  for  increases  in  the  labor  force  to  be  absorbed  in  trade 
and  services  rather  than  in  industry  was  most  marked  in  Italy  where  the 
total  active  population  increase  between  1931  and  1949  was  17  per  cent; 
the  increase  in  employment  in  trade  and  banking  was  36  per  cent  and  in 
other  services  41  per  cent.  The  contrast  in  this  respect  between  the  north- 
ern and  western  countries  of  Europe  and  those  of  southern  Europe  was 
analyzed  by  the  Economic  Commission  for  Europe  in  a  way  which  under- 
scores the  economic  factors  that  make  for  a  dynamic  balanced  growth  on 
the  one  hand,  and  those  that  produce  stagnation  or  decay. 

After  noting  that  the  agricultural  population  has  declined  in  northern 

39  Population  and  labor  force  estimates  from  Trends  in  Economic  Growth,  p.  6. 

40  OEEC,  op.  cit.,  Vol.  1,  p.  179. 


THE  ECONOMIC  CAPABILITIES  OF  WESTERN  EUROPE        555 

and  western  Europe  "where  industry  was  already  dominant  in  1930"  and 
increased  in  the  countries  in  which  agriculture  predominated,  the  ECE 
pointed  out  that  per  capita  national  income  is  much  higher  in  the  former 
countries  and  thus  the  possibilities  for  savings  and  investment  are  much 
greater.  Increases  in  population  are  absorbed  in  industry  and  other  urban 
occupations,  and  because  per  capita  incomes  are  high,  the  proportion  of 
increases  in  incomes  which  goes  for  food  consumption  is  relatively  low, 
and  can  be  met  by  imports  paid  for  by  expanded  exports  of  manufactures. 
Thus  increases  in  the  labor  supply  are  matched  by  investment  and  eco- 
nomic growth,  and  industrial  expansion  is  relatively  easy. 

In  southern  Europe,  on  the  other  hand,  savings  are  low  and  enterprise 
is  lacking.  Government  investment  is  inhibited  by  fear  of  inflation.  A  large 
proportion  of  increments  to  incomes  goes  for  food,  of  which  the  domestic 
supply  is  inelastic  and  cannot  easily  be  supplemented  by  imports  because 
of  existing  pressure  on  the  balance-of -payments.  Industrial  production  is 
mostly  for  the  home  market,  and  is  not  competitive  in  foreign  markets. 
Land  reform  only  aggravates  the  problem:  "Land  reforms  which  increase 
total  output  on  the  land  only  slightly,  and  result  mainly  in  more  man- 
power being  used  for  producing  nearly  the  same  quantities  as  before  or 
which  create  too  small  holdings,  are  a  poor  substitute  for  transfer  of  the 
surplus  population  to  industry."  41 

Thus  in  considerable  part  the  future  economic  growth  of  Western 
Europe  depends  on  finding  more  productive  employment  for  the  partially 
and  less  productively  employed  workers  in  southern  Europe.  In  the  words 
of  theOEEC:  42 

A  surplus  agricultural  population  may  be  reduced  by  a  movement  of  workers 
hitherto  employed  in  agriculture  to  other  sectors;  but  the  reduction  may  also  be 
very  largely  achieved  by  the  movement  into  other  sectors  of  workers  taking  their 
first  jobs.  This  movement  does  not  necessarily  involve  a  concentration  of  the 
population  in  large  towns.  Industries  and  services  more  or  less  related  to  agri- 
culture may  develop  in  rural  areas.  Movements  from  agriculture  to  more  pro- 
ductive sectors  have  in  fact  been  steady  and  rapid  in  the  wealthiest  countries, 
where  they  have  contributed  considerably  to  the  improvement  in  standards  of 
living;  but  they  have  been  slower  in  other  countries  owing  to  delayed  industrial- 
isation or,  since  the  war,  to  the  housing  shortage.  Insofar  as  such  countries  are 
able  to  pursue  expansionary  policies,  these  should  aim  at  increased  industrialisa- 
tion and  quicker  removal  of  the  housing  shortage. 

Productivity  per  man-hour  in  Western  European  industry  has  been  less 
than  in  the  United  States  since  the  beginning  of  the  century  and  is  now 

41  ECE,  Economic  Survey  of  Europe  Since  the  War,  pp.  154,  155. 

42  Ibid. 


556        THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

between  one-fourth  and  one-half  of  that  in  the  United  States.  Moreover, 
it  is  not  catching  up,  although  it  is  increasing  much  more  than  in  the 
Soviet  Union.  Between  1938  and  1954  the  increase  in  real  gross  national 
product  per  man  hour  of  employment  was  about  15  per  cent.  The  in- 
creases in  manufacturing  industry  over  the  best  prewar  years  range  from 
about  4  per  cent  in  France  and  7  per  cent  in  Germany  to  29  per  cent  in 
the  United  Kingdom.  Increases  in  agriculture  may  have  been  somewhat 
higher.  Productivity  per  man  hour  in  the  United  States  in  1954  was  about 
40  per  cent  above  pre-war  in  industry  and  in  agriculture  has  more  than 
doubled.43 

As  contrasted  with  the  United  States,  an  inferior  and  less-balanced  re- 
source endowment  in  Western  Europe  has  probably  had  some  effect  in 
retarding  the  growth  of  efficiency.  Until  relatively  recently  the  American 
economy  found  most  of  its  raw  materials  and  energy  at  home,  while  the 
availability  of  land  on  the  expanding  frontier  kept  the  price  of  labor  rela- 
tively high  and  encouraged  mechanization  and  the  use  of  capital.  These 
factors  also  contributed  to  a  psychology  of  "progress"  and  efficiency 
whereas  in  many  European  countries  traditional  attitudes  favored  stability 
rather  than  change. 

The  nineteenth  century  is  usually  thought  of  as  a  period  in  which  the 
philosophy  of  laissez-faire  and  economic  liberalism  prevailed,  not  only  in 
the  United  Kingdom  but  across  Europe.  However,  this  is  not  wholly  the 
case.  The  economic  liberalism  of  the  Manchester  school  was  transplanted 
to  the  continent  to  thrive  only  briefly  and  was  succeeded  after  1875  by  a 
growing  spirit  of  "neo-mercantilism"  under  which  industry,  agriculture, 
and  trade  were  regarded  as  national  interests,  to  be  protected  by  tariff, 
subsidies,  licensing,  and  other  restrictive  measures.44 

The  prevalence  of  such  attitudes  toward  economic  progress  varies 
among  the  different  countries  of  Europe.  It  is  probably  most  marked  in 
France  and  least  conspicuous  in  postwar  Germany,  once  the  stronghold  of 
neo-mercantilism.  It  is  not  absent  in  the  United  Kingdom  where,  under 
a  Labor  government,  what  the  London  Economist  called  the  "theory  and 
practise  of  capitalism"  was  for  a  while  abandoned  in  favor  of  raising  the 
standard  of  living  through  redistribution  of  income.45  This  characteriza- 
tion of  the  United  Kingdom  as  "consumption-minded"  rather  than  capital- 
conscious  might  have  been  applied  with  equal  force  to  almost  the  whole 
of  Europe  except  Germany  and  the  Low  Countries. 

43  Ibid.,  p.  61. 

44  Hayes,  op.  cit.,  32-37. 

45  The  Economist,  October  16,  1954,  pp.  191-92. 


THE  ECONOMIC  CAPABILITIES  OF  WESTERN  EUROPE        557 

SIZE  OF  THE  EUROPEAN  MARKET 

An  important  factor  in  promoting  efficiency  in  the  American  economy 
was  the  large  size  of  the  market  and  the  absence  of  restrictions  on  the 
movement  of  workers  and  goods  from  one  region  to  the  other.  For  most 
Western  European  countries,  a  much  larger  part  of  their  market  is  in  other 
countries  of  Europe  as  well  as  other  parts  of  the  world.  The  protective 
tariffs  of  the  later  nineteenth  and  early  twentieth  century  prevented 
Western  Europe  from  taking  the  maximum  advantage  of  specialization 
and  intra-European  trade.  These  restrictions  were  aggravated  in  the  thir- 
ties by  quantitative  restrictions  on  imports  and  the  growing  practice  of 
bilateral  trade  balancing.  Hence  one  of  the  principal  tasks  of  the  OEEC 
in  the  postwar  period  has  been  the  "liberalization"  of  intra-European 
trade.  Since  a  larger  international  machinery  under  the  General  Agree- 
ment on  Tariffs  and  Trade  has  been  established  for  the  purpose  of  reduc- 
ing tariff  barriers,  the  OEEC  has  concentrated  on  the  removal  of  quanti- 
tative restrictions  on  imports  of  member  countries  from  other  member 
countries.  Most  progress  has  been  made  with  the  liberalization  of  raw 
materials  imports.  Some  member  countries  have  been  reluctant  to  liberal- 
ize imports  of  manufactured  goods  for  "balance-of-payments"  reasons  and 
an  even  greater  reluctance  to  liberalize  agricultural  imports  is  frankly 
attributed  by  many  countries  to  their  desire  to  protect  domestic  agricul- 
ture on  both  social  and  strategic  grounds. 

STEPS  TOWARD  THE  INTEGRATION  OF  THE 
EUROPEAN  ECONOMY 

Bilateralism  has  been  practically  eliminated  from  intra-European  trade 
( except  for  trade  with  the  countries  of  Eastern  Europe )  by  the  European 
Payments  Union  ( EPU )  which  ensures  the  transferability  between  mem- 
ber countries  of  the  Western  European  currencies  (including  sterling) 
received  by  each  of  these  countries  from  the  others,  including  the  terri- 
tories in  their  monetary  areas.  The  importance  of  the  EPU  is  shown  by 
the  fact  that  one-fourth  of  all  the  visible  trade  of  the  world  is  settled 
through  the  Union  with  only  a  very  small  settlement  of  balances  in  gold 
or  dollars.46 

Other  arrangements  which  have  been  made  to  widen  the  European 
market  include  the  formation  of  the  Benelux  (Belgium,  Netherlands, 
Luxembourg)  customs  union  and  the  European  Coal  and  Steel  Commu- 

*e  OEEC,  op.  cit.,  139. 


558       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

nity.  In  Benelux  all  customs  duties  (and  almost  all  quantitative  restric- 
tions )  within  the  area  have  been  abolished,  and  a  common  tariff  vis-a-vis 
third  countries  was  adopted.  Since  its  establishment  in  September,  1944, 
Benelux  has  weathered  a  number  of  storms  and  has  accomplished  a  cer- 
tain degree  of  economic  integration.  It  thus  becomes  imperative  to 
the  student  of  political  and  economic  geography  to  view  the  economic  and 
political  systems  of  these  three  member  states  in  close  union.  This  integra- 
tion is  even  more  significant  if  one  considers  the  fact  that  Holland  and 
Belgium  have  highly  different  economies.  Belgium  found  itself  in  a  much 
more  favorable  situation  in  the  postwar  period  than  Holland,  which  had 
to  repair  its  war  damages  (to  say  nothing  of  damages  in  1953  when 
flood  waters  engulfed  350,000  acres  of  land)  and  which  had  to  recover 
from  the  serious  shock  caused  by  the  loss  of  its  colonial  empire  in  the 
Netherlands  Indies. 

The  European  Coal  and  Steel  Community  (ECSC)  has  been  estab- 
lished by  a  treaty  as  a  European  federal  institution  to  pool  the  coal  and 
steel  resources  of  the  six  participating  countries— West  Germany,  France, 
Belgium,  Luxembourg,  the  Netherlands,  and  Italy.  It  prohibits  cartels  and 
removes  barriers  to  the  movement  of  coal,  steel  products,  and  workers 
among  member  countries.  This  treaty  has  created  a  common  market  with- 
out tariffs  and  quantitative  restrictions  in  the  most  important  sector  of 
European  trade  and  is  regarded  by  many  as  the  first  significant  step  to- 
ward the  unification  and  integration  of  the  western  European  economies. 
It  has  been  hailed  by  some  as  heralding  the  eventual  establishment  of  a 
European  political  federation.  Even  if  the  operation  of  the  Coal  and  Steel 
Community  were  only  extended,  as  has  been  proposed,  to  other  trade  be- 
tween the  members,  this  would  be  a  major  accomplishment  in  the  direc- 
tion of  European  economic  integration  since  the  six  member  countries 
cover  450,000  square  miles  and  include  160  million  people.47 

Still  in  the  planning  stage  but  likely  to  become  a  reality  in  the  future 
is  a  Scandinavian  customs  union.  This  would  unite  the  nations  of  the 
Nordic  Council— Denmark,  Norway,  Sweden,  and  Iceland— in  an  organiza- 
tion which,  following  the  successful  model  of  the  Scandinavian  Airlines 
System,  would  bring  about  joint  enterprises  in  such  industries  as  steel, 
chemicals,  and  textiles.  Thus,  as  a  first  step  towards  a  customs  union,  the 
necessary  conditions  for  a  common  market  in  certain  goods  would  be 
created.48 

47  For  further  information  see  Foreign  Operations  Administration,  Monthly  Oper- 
ations Report,  June  30,  1954;  also  OEEC,  op.  cit.,  pp.  137-138. 

48  The  Economist,  1954,  pp.  671-672. 


THE  ECONOMIC  CAPABILITIES  OF  WESTERN  EUROPE        559 

Although  the  result  of  all  these  measures  has  been  to  expand  intra- 
European  trade  well  beyond  the  expectations  entertained  at  the  beginning 
of  the  Marshall  Plan  in  1948,  when  no  significant  increase  was  expected, 
the  share  of  intra-European  trade  in  the  total  foreign  trade  of  Western 
European  countries  remains  about  the  same  as  in  the  prewar  period.  It  is 
clear  that  a  marked  expansion  in  regional  trade  relative  to  trade  with  the 
rest  of  the  world  will  require  more  intensive  programs. 


SPECIAL  PROBLEMS— ENERGY 

Coal  production  in  Western  Europe  has  not  increased  above  the  prewar 
level  and  presents  a  serious  structural  problem.  Up  to  World  War  I,  West- 
ern Europe  as  a  whole  was  a  net  exporter  of  energy  in  the  form  of  coal  and 
coal  bunkers,  mainly  from  the  United  Kingdom.  After  World  War  I,  and 
especially  since  the  1930's,  the  tendency  has  been  towards  stability  or  even 
contraction  in  the  demand  for  coal  due  to  the  substitution  of  other  fuels 
and  water  power,  and  to  increased  efficiency  in  the  use  of  solid  fuels. 
Depletion  of  the  better  seams  has  tended  to  increase  costs  and  it  has  been 
difficult  to  obtain  increases  in  productivity.  It  is  not  likely  that  further  im- 
provements in  the  utilization  of  coal  will  be  sufficient  to  offset  the  failure 
of  output  to  rise.  Stagnation  in  the  coal-mining  industry  has  created  con- 
siderable problems  in  a  number  of  communities,  but  especially  in  the 
United  Kingdom  where  the  mines  are  old,  deep,  scattered,  and  difficult  to 
mechanize,  and  where  mounting  costs  and  the  drift  of  miners  into  other 
occupations  has  tended  to  keep  production  below  even  the  reduced  de- 
mand. This  has  prompted  the  government  to  embark  on  the  most  ambi- 
tious program  for  producing  electricity  from  atomic  reactors  that  any 
country  has  yet  devised. 

Coal  production  in  France,  similarly,  although  slightly  above  the  pre- 
war level  is  still  below  the  production  target  of  60  million  tons  set  by  the 
Monnet  five-year  plan.  France  has  40,000  fewer  miners  than  in  the  thirties, 
and  costs  are  mounting.  Despite  the  growing  use  of  petroleum,  the  de- 
mand for  coal  in  Europe  may  for  some  time  tend  to  outstrip  European 
production  and  to  require  imports.  As  a  result  discussions  have  begun 
both  in  the  Coal  and  Steel  Community  and  in  the  OEEC  looking  toward 
the  development  of  a  unified  atomic  energy  program  to  supplement  con- 
ventional sources  of  energy. 

Western  Europe's  difficulty  in  expanding  coal  production  is  com- 
pounded by  the  failure  to  find  petroleum  in  any  considerable  amounts. 
However,  the  United  Kingdom,  France,  and  other  OEEC  countries  have 


560       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

for  balance-of-payments  reasons  expanded  their  own  refinery  capacity 
with  a  view  to  reducing  imports  of  products  in  favor  of  increased  imports 
of  lower  cost  crude  petroleum.  Imports  of  products  into  the  United  King- 
dom, France,  Germany,  Italy,  and  the  Netherlands,  for  example,  fell  from 
17.5  million  tons  in  1948  to  12.9  million  tons  in  1951,  while  in  the  same 
period  the  same  countries  increased  their  imports  of  crude  petroleum 
from  15.4  million  tons  to  51.2  million.49  In  1953,  for  the  first  time,  some 
net  exports  of  refined  products  took  place;  Western  Europe  imported  8.2 
million  tons  of  products  and  exported  9.4  million  tons  (in  addition  to 
intra-European  trade  of  16.6  million  tons).50 

Western  Europe's  petroleum  requirements  are  increasing  at  a  rate  of 
10  to  15  per  cent  annually.  The  refineries  of  Western  Europe  are  almost 
wholly  dependent  on  crude  oil  from  the  Middle  East  producing  countries 
such  as  Iran,  Kuwait,  Iraq  and  Saudi  Arabia.  The  crude  oil  is  transported 
to  the  Eastern  Mediterranean  by  pipeline  or  through  the  Suez  canal  and 
then  generally  by  tanker  to  the  refining  centers.  This  dependence  on 
Middle  East  oil  to  supply  Europe's  rapidly  growing  energy  demands,  and 
the  apparent  vulnerability  of  transportation  arrangements  in  the  area  is 
one  of  the  reasons  why  Western  European  countries,  especially  the  United 
Kingdom  and  France,  are  anxious  to  preserve  peace  in  that  region. 

AGRICULTURE 

By  1953-54  agricultural  output  in  Western  Europe  (OEEC  countries) 
had  risen  to  129  per  cent  of  the  best  prewar  levels,  which  is  an  increase 
of  about  14  per  cent  on  a  per  capita  basis.  A  number  of  factors  contributed 
to  the  increase,  among  them  increased  use  of  fertilizers  and  machinery, 
seed  selection,  and  better  livestock  production  methods.  Perhaps  most 
impressive  is  a  16  per  cent  increase  in  livestock  products  compared  with 
prewar  levels,  accomplished  despite  a  30  per  cent  reduction  in  imports 
of  feed.51 

As  indicated  earlier,  however,  there  is  in  many  continental  Western 
European  countries  a  great  need  for  improved  productivity  in  agriculture, 
and  for  the  release  of  manpower  to  other  employments.  A  number  of  fac- 
tors appear  to  be  interfering  with  more  efficient  land  utilization  and  pro- 
ductivity. An  important  obstacle  is  the  very  considerable  fragmentation  of 
agricultural  land  (small  average  size  of  plots),  averaging  from  less  than 

49  ECE,  Economic  Survey  of  Europe  Since  the  War,  pp.  298-99. 

50  The  Economist,  November  20,  1954,  p.  674. 

51  OEEC,  op.  cit.,  p.  55. 


THE  ECONOMIC  CAPABILITIES  OF  WESTERN  EUROPE        561 

one  hectare  in  Belgium,  Switzerland,  and  West  Germany,  to  two  or  three 
in  the  Netherlands,  southwest  France,  and  Spain.  However,  the  averages 
do  not  tell  the  whole  story.  About  six  million  hectares  of  farm  land  are 
estimated  by  the  Food  and  Agriculture  Organization  to  be  in  need  of 
consolidation  in  West  Germany  and  Italy,  and  as  much  as  nine  million 
in  France  and  twelve  million  in  Spain.52 

Another  obstacle  to  more  efficient  agriculture  is  the  high  degree  of 
government  protection,  expressed  in  tariff  and  quantitative  restrictions  on 
imports.  Aside  from  imports  of  cereals,  sugar,  fibers,  and  vegetable  oils, 
most  "Western  European  countries  have  chosen  ...  to  protect  and  main- 
tain their  agricultural  structure  composed  of  millions  of  small  farmers, 
reserving  for  them  virtually  the  whole  of  the  market  for  animal  products 
and  most  of  that  for  vegetables  and  fruits."  53 

The  desirability  of  liberalizing  and  enlarging  the  European  market  for 
agricultural  products  and  promoting  greater  specialization  has  been  rec- 
ognized by  members  of  the  OEEC.  Proposals  have  been  made  for  the 
creation  of  a  "green  pool,"  a  federal  institution  similar  to  the  Coal-Steel 
Community  to  integrate  the  markets  of  member  countries  and  relax  re- 
strictions on  the  sale  and  movement  of  agricultural  products  among  them. 
These  proposals  have  been  dropped  but  further  consideration  is  being 
given  to  the  matter  under  auspices  of  the  OEEC.£ 


54 


EXTERNAL  FACTORS  AFFECTING  WESTERN  EUROPE'S 

ECONOMIC  GROWTH 

As  noted  above  this  division  into  internal  and  external  factors  affect- 
ing Western  Europe's  economic  outlook  is  somewhat  arbitrary  because  the 
two  sets  of  factors  contain  forces  acting  on  one  another  in  a  reciprocal 
relationship.  Thus,  the  depression  of  the  early  thirties  with  its  adverse 
effect  on  the  demand  for,  and  prices  of,  foodstuffs  and  raw  materials 
helped  to  motivate  primary  producing  countries  to  shift  resources  in  the 
direction  of  their  own  industrialization.  The  consequences  of  this  in  the 
period  after  World  War  II  are  seen  in  reduced  export  availabilities  of 
primary  products  from  these  countries  and  a  shift  in  their  demand  away 
from  consumer  goods,  especially  textiles,  which  are  one  of  Western  Eu- 
rope's (and  the  United  Kingdom's)  most  important  exports,  in  favor  of  an 

52  Trends  in  Economic  Growth,  p.  109. 

53  United  Nations  Food  and  Agriculture  Organization,  European  Agriculture— A 
Statement  of  Problem  (Geneva,  1954),  p.  2. 

54  Trends  in  Economic  Growth,  p.  110.  See  also  Economic  Survey  of  Europe  Since 
the  War,  pp.  233,  234. 


562       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

increased  demand  for  capital  goods  of  the  latest  design,  especially  from 
the  United  States.  The  position  of  Western  Europe  in  the  world  economy 
has  undergone  a  number  of  such  changes  since  1913  and  these  changes 
are  sometimes  called  structural  changes  to  denote  their  deep-rooted  and 
irrevocable  character.55 

To  trace  these  changes  and  their  manifold  interrelationships  carefully 
would  require  an  extended  discussion  going  beyond  the  scope  of  this 
chapter.56  However,  the  principal  trends  can  be  delineated  adequately  if 
we  examine  ( a )  the  long-term  change  in  the  share  of  Western  Europe  in 
world  trade  and  some  of  the  reasons  therefor,  and  ( b )  the  trade  and  pay- 
ments position  of  Western  Europe  in  the  decade  after  World  War  II.  At 
this  time,  the  effects  both  of  certain  structural  changes  and  of  the  disor- 
ganization of  the  war  combined  to  create  a  situation  in  which  Western 
Europe's  receipts  from  abroad,  particularly  of  dollars,  were  quite  insuffi- 
cient to  maintain  a  reasonable  level  of  imports. 

DECLINE  IN  WESTERN  EUROPE'S  SHARE  OF  WORLD  TRADE 

Along  with  the  decline  of  the  relative  importance  of  the  Western  Euro- 
pean economy  after  World  War  I  went  a  decline  in  Western  Europe'  share 
of  total  world  trade.  In  terms  of  total  world  exports  Europe's  share  shrank 
from  more  than  50  per  cent  before  World  War  I  to  45  per  cent  in  the  inter- 
war  period  and  to  about  35  per  cent  in  1948-50.57  Another  way  of  express- 
ing this  change  is  in  terms  of  shares  in  total  trade:  trade  between  non- 
European  countries,  which  was  only  25  per  cent  of  total  trade  in  the 
period  1909  to  1913,  rose  to  40  per  cent  in  the  period  1925-38,  and  to  50 
per  cent  in  1948-50.  At  the  same  time  intra-European  trade  declined  from 
about  one-third  of  total  world  trade  to  about  one-fifth. 

Most  of  this  decline  in  the  interwar  period  represented  a  loss  of  exports 
by  the  three  big  European  trading  nations,  the  United  Kingdom,  Ger- 
many, and  France,  whose  share  of  total  European  exports  fell  between 
1913  and  1938  from  about  64  per  cent  to  52  per  cent. 

The  most  obvious  explanation  for  the  declining  importance  of  Western 
Europe  in  world  trade  was  the  growing  importance  of  other  trading  na- 
tions, particularly  the  United  States  and  Japan.  An  important  factor  con- 
tributing to  this  development,  especially  with  regard  to  the  United  States 
but  by  no  means  the  only  one,  was  the  interruption  caused  to  Europe's 

55  ECE,  Economic  Survey  of  Europe  Since  the  War,  p.  10. 

56  See  ibid.,  Chs.  2,  6  and  7,  also  ECE,  Growth  and  Stagnation  in  the  European 
Economy,  especially  Chs.  2  and  9. 

57  ECE,  Growth  and  Stagnation  in  the  European  Economy,  pp.  168-170. 


THE  ECONOMIC  CAPABILITIES  OF  WESTERN  EUROPE        563 

trade  by  two  world  wars.  In  the  interwar  period,  moreover,  there  were 
important  shifts  in  the  commodity  pattern  of  world  trade,  which  may  be 
summarized  by  saying  that  ( as  percentages  of  total  imports )  the  demand 
for  textiles  and  miscellaneous  manufactures  fell,  the  demand  for  metals 
and  chemicals  was  relatively  stable,  while  the  demand  for  machinery  and 
transport  equipment  (including  motor  cars)  rose.  The  declining  volume 
of  textile  exports  from  Western  Europe  attributable  to  the  growth  of 
domestic  textile  production  in  overseas  areas  and  to  increasing  competi- 
tion from  Japan,  the  United  States,  and  India  ( that  is,  textile  exports  from 
Europe  were  a  declining  proportion  of  a  shrinking  total  trade),  was  espe- 
cially injurious  to  the  trade  of  the  United  Kingdom,  Germany,  France, 
Belgium,  and  Switzerland.  On  the  other  hand,  the  benefit  of  the  increased 
demand  for  machinery  and  transport  equipment  went  largely  to  the 
United  States. 

The  relationships  described  merely  suggest  what  a  more  detailed  analy- 
sis would  show:  that  the  European  countries  because  of  the  effects  of 
World  War  I  and  of  various  rigidities  in  their  industrial  systems  reacted 
only  very  slowly  in  the  interwar  period  to  large  and  rapidly  moving 
changes  in  the  commodity  pattern  of  world  demand.  After  1938  the  evi- 
dence suggests  that  the  indicated  adaptations  were  being  made;  in  any 
case  by  1950  Western  Europe  had  regained  its  1938  position  in  total  world 
trade,  and  after  1950,  in  particular  by  virtue  of  the  rapid  expansion  of 
German  exports,  had  recovered  even  more  lost  ground.58  Moreover,  the 
United  Kingdom,  France,  and  Germany  have  regained  their  1913  relative 
positions  in  total  European  exports. 

EUROPE'S  POSTWAR  PAYMENTS  PROBLEM 

While  there  is  therefore  some  reason  to  think  that  Western  Europe  has 
the  capability  of  recovering  some  of  its  former  pre-eminence  in  world 
trade,  there  remain  certain  structural  imbalances  in  the  pattern  of  world 
trade,  in  part  the  legacy  of  World  War  II,  which  continue  to  confront 
Western  Europe  with  the  elements  of  the  "dollar  problem."  Even  before 
World  War  II  Western  Europe  had  a  deficit  on  current  account  with  the 
dollar  area  59  estimated  at  about  $2  billion  in  1953  prices.  In  the  general 
system  of  convertible  currencies  and  multilateral  settlements  which  then 
prevailed,  this  deficit  was  made  up  with  dollars  earned  by  European  ex- 
ports to  third  areas  having  dollar  surpluses  resulting,  for  example,  from 

58  OEEC,  op.  cit.,  p.  93. 

59  The  United  States,  Canada,  Mexico,  Venezuela,  Colombia,  the  Caribbean  and 
Central  American  Republics,  and  the  Philippines. 


564       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

rubber  and  tin  sales  from  Southeast  Asia  and  gold  sales  from  South  Africa. 
After  World  War  II  a  number  of  factors  combined  to  make  it  difficult 
to  achieve  balance  in  Western  Europe's  external  accounts  and  next  to 
impossible  to  impose  balance  in  the  dollar  accounts.  These  factors,  in 
effect,  operated  to  reduce  Western  Europe's  real  income  and  to  make  it 
necessary  to  expand  commodity  exports  very  considerably  while  econo- 
mizing to  the  maximum  on  imports.  Very  briefly  the  new  factors  were  the 
following: 

Western  Europe's  capital  position  deteriorated  very  badly  as  a  result 
of  the  war.  Long-term  investments,  especially  in  the  United  States,  had 
been  sold.  Large  sterling  debts  were  incurred  during  the  war  to  obtain 
wartime  goods  and  services  in  India,  Egypt,  and  other  countries,  and  large 
dollar  debts  were  incurred  by  the  United  Kingdom  and  France  in  1946 
and  1947.  Revenue  from  shipping,  insurance,  and  other  commercial  and 
financial  services  was  adversely  affected  by  new  competition,  while  over- 
seas military  expenditures  for  the  United  Kingdom  and  France  were 
greatly  increased.  The  greatest  burden  of  all  was  that  imposed  by  the  shift 
in  the  terms  of  trade  which  because  of  reduced  export  availabilities  of 
foodstuffs  and  raw  materials  increased  the  prices  of  imports  relative  to  the 
prices  of  Western  Europe's  exports. 

Meanwhile  partly  as  the  result  of  the  war  and  partly  as  the  result  of 
political,  social,  and  technological  changes,  the  supplies  of  raw  materials 
and  foodstuffs  from  the  dollar  area  increased  while  similar  supplies  from 
the  sterling  area  and  other  non-dollar  sources  tended  to  decline.  Thus 
wartime  demands  stimulated  production  of  foodstuffs  hi  North  America, 
aluminum  from  the  dollar  area  increased  in  importance  relative  to  sterling 
area  tin  and  lead,  imports  of  dollar  petroleum  increased.  At  the  same  time 
in  many  countries  inflation  and  population  increases  swelled  domestic 
consumption  at  the  expense  of  exports,  and  resources  were  shifted  away 
from  the  production  of  foodstuffs  for  export  to  industrial  development— 
as  notably  in  Argentina  and  Australia.  These  developments  all  tended  to 
shift  Europe's  imports  from  non-dollar  to  dollar  sources  but  without  any 
corresponding  rise  in  receipts  from  the  dollar  area.  Most  of  the  wartime 
and  postwar  increase  in  imports  of  the  United  States  was  in  commodities 
originating  in  the  Western  Hemisphere,  such  as  coffee,  timber  and  paper, 
aluminum,  and  petroleum. 


THE  ECONOMIC  CAPABILITIES  OF  WESTERN  EUROPE        565 
THE  MARSHALL  PLAN 

As  a  consequence  of  these  developments,  unless  Western  Europe  was  to 
cut  its  imports  below  the  levels  needed  to  maintain  employment  and  pro- 
duction, a  deficit  in  the  dollar  balance-of -payments  was  inevitable— a  defi- 
cit beyond  the  capacity  of  Western  European  countries  to  finance  from 
their  scanty  reserves  of  gold  and  dollars.  It  was  this  situation  which  led 
to  the  Marshall  plan  under  which  the  United  States  financed  the  dollar 
deficit  in  Western  Europe's  balance-of-payments  during  the  period  1948- 
52  and  permitted  some  reconstitution  of  Western  Europe's  gold  and  dollar 
reserves. 

The  dollar  problem  has  temporarily  disappeared  although  there  are 
grounds  for  believing  that  it  has  not  been  completely  excised.  The  chief 
factor  in  its  disappearance  is  the  large  volume  of  dollar  payments  to  West- 
ern Europe  resulting  from  military  expenditures  in  connection  with  the 
stationing  of  United  States  forces  in  Europe,  and  United  States  procure- 
ment of  military  goods  and  services.  A  high  proportion  of  these  expendi- 
tures, it  is  true,  may  become  a  fairly  permanent  feature  of  United  States 
participation  under  NATO  in  the  arrangements  for  the  defense  of  Western 
Europe.  In  the  absence  of  these  payments,  however,  and  with  the  termi- 
nation of  United  States  economic  assistance  to  Western  Europe,  the  dol- 
lar-payments position  of  Western  Europe  would  once  again  be  somewhat 
precarious.  In  the  long  run,  strength  in  the  European  payments  situation 
depends  on  the  continued  expansion  of  exportable  supplies  of  foodstuffs 
and  raw  materials  in  non-dollar  areas.  The  loss  of  colonial  possessions  and 
the  reduced  ability  of  the  metropolitan  countries  of  Western  Europe  to  in- 
fluence the  character  of  overseas  economic  development  through  capital 
exports,  coupled  with  the  drive  for  industrial  development  and  autarky  in 
the  primary  producing  countries  makes  the  long-run  outlook  at  best  un- 
certain. 

E.    Summary  and  Conclusions 

Western  Europe  has  lost  its  former  position  of  industrial  and  commer- 
cial supremacy  and  with  this  loss  has  gone  a  decline  in  her  world-power 
position  and  a  significant  loss  of  colonial  possessions.  However,  the  pros- 
pect is  not  one  of  unrelieved  stagnation  or  decay.  The  favorable  endow- 
ments of  climate,  geography,  and  natural  resources  remain,  as  does  the 
heritage  of  unparalleled  cultural,  scientific,  and  technical  achievement. 
The  population  and  labor  force  are  growing  although  not  as  rapidly  as  in 
the  United  States  or  the  U.S.S.R.  There  are  encouraging  possibilities  for 


566       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

greatly  strengthening  the  European  economy  through  modernization  of 
agriculture  and  widening  of  the  European  market.  The  principal  obstacles 
to  the  future  and  continuing  growth  of  Europe's  economic  capabilities  lie 
in  the  sphere  of  external  economic  relations.  Europe  must  expand  its  ex- 
ports of  manufactured  goods  in  third  areas  in  competition  with  those  of 
the  United  States  ( and  Japan )  in  order  to  command  the  growing  amounts 
of  raw  materials  and  foodstuffs  that  will  be  needed.  These  areas  must  in 
turn  continue  to  offer  for  sale  to  Western  Europe  on  reasonable  terms  the 
needed  foodstuffs  and  raw  materials.  Purchases  by  Western  Europe  of 
raw  materials  and  foodstuffs  from  the  dollar  area  must  be  kept  within  the 
limits  set  by  Western  Europe's  ability  to  earn  dollars  (a)  by  exports  of 
goods  and  services  to  the  protected  United  States  market,  ( b )  by  exports 
of  manufactures  to  dollar-surplus  primary  producing  countries  (as  Ma- 
laya), and  (c)  through  United  States  military  expenditures  in  NATO 
countries. 

Since  1950  the  evidence  has  increasingly  demonstrated  Western  Eu- 
rope's capacity  to  make  the  indicated  adjustments.  Even  if  this  progress  is 
sustained,  however,  there  is  little  likelihood  of  Europe  regaining  the  rela- 
tive economic  capabilities  on  which  its  world  supremacy  at  the  end  of  the 
Victorian  age  was  founded.  There  is,  moreover,  every  indication  that  the 
over-all  economic  capabilities  of  the  Soviet  bloc,  which  are  now  not  far 
exceeded  by  those  of  all  Western  European  countries  combined,  will  in 
the  next  two  decades  surpass  them.  The  importance  of  Western  Europe's 
economic  capabilities,  then,  must  be  viewed  in  the  light  of  the  contribu- 
tion they  make  to  aggregate  Western  capabilities  rather-  than  in  them- 
selves. To  the  extent,  therefore,  that  power  relationships  continue  to 
depend  on  relative  economic  capabilities  (as  opposed  to  new  factors 
introduced  by  the  possession  of  nuclear  weapons),  Western  Europe's 
future  lies  not  in  an  independent  course  but  is  bound  up  with  the  fortunes 
of  the  Western  alliance. 


CHAPTER 


18 


The  United  States  and  Canad 


A.    The  United  States 

The  United  States  occupies  a  dominant  position  in  the  world  economy. 
With  only  about  6  per  cent  of  the  world's  population  it  accounted  for 
almost  40  per  cent  of  the  world's  output  of  goods  and  services  in  1954. 
This  was  almost  twice  the  production  of  all  of  Free  Europe  or  of  the 
entire  Soviet  bloc,  including  Communist  China. 

By  virtue  of  its  great  economic  strength  the  United  States  plays  a  major 
role  in  world  economy.  In  1954  the  United  States  accounted  for  20  per 
cent  of  the  world's  exports  and  14  per  cent  of  its  imports.  The  United 
States  is  the  world's  largest  creditor  nation  and  the  principal  supplier  of 
capital  for  overseas  investment.  It  is  little  wonder,  therefore,  that  this 
country's  domestic  and  foreign  economic  policies  are  of  vital  concern  to 
other  countries. 

The  enormous  economic  capabilities  of  the  United  States  largely  ac- 
count for  its  position  as  the  leading  world  power.  World  War  II  demon- 
strated the  awesome  military  force  which  these  capabilities  are  able  to 
support.  In  1944  at  the  peak  of  the  war  effort  the  United  States  produced 
45  per  cent  of  the  armaments  of  all  the  belligerents.  The  United  States 
was  truly  the  arsenal  of  democracy.  The  resources  of  the  United  States 
have  become  an  important  instrument  of  national  power  in  peace  as  well 
as  in  war.  They  have  been  used  on  a  lavish  scale  to  restore  the  war- 
devastated  economies  of  friendly  as  well  as  former  enemy  powers  and  to 
bolster  up  the  economic  and  military  strength  of  the  Free  World.  Eco- 
nomic power  is  of  course  only  one  of  the  ingredients  of  national  power, 

567 


568       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

but  in  the  hands  of  the  United  States  it  has  become  a  major  instrument  of 
statecraft. 

As  with  other  areas,  geographical  factors  cannot  entirely  explain  the 
course  and  pattern  of  United  States'  economic  development.  Nonetheless, 
this  chapter  suggests  that  favorable  geographical  factors  such  as  rich 
natural  resources,  climate  and  terrain,  and  world  location  have  been  more 
important  for  the  economic  development  of  the  United  States  than  for  any 
other  nation  except  possibly  the  Soviet  Union. 

GEOGRAPHY  AND  PEOPLE 

Geography.  The  United  States,  with  a  land  area  of  roughly  3  million 
square  miles,  is  the  third  largest  nation  in  the  Western  Hemisphere; 
Canada  is  the  largest  and  Brazil  is  the  second  largest.  It  is  bounded  in  the 
north  by  Canada,  in  the  south  by  Mexico,  and  includes  most  of  North 
America  between  30  degrees  and  49  degrees  north  latitude.  "Separated 
by  some  3,000  miles  of  the  Atlantic  Ocean  from  Europe,  with  its  inter- 
national problems,  and  by  5,000  miles  of  the  Pacific  Ocean  from  the  coun- 
tries of  eastern  Asia  .  . .  the  U.S.A.  has  tended  until  recently  to  isolate 
herself  from  commitments  overseas. .  .  ."  1  Its  relative  isolation  from  other 
major  centers  of  power  has  of  course  been  a  great  strategic  advantage  to 
the  United  States,  since  the  danger  of  foreign  invasion  was  virtually  elim- 
inated. As  a  result,  the  United  States,  like  the  United  Kingdom  in  an 
earlier  era,  was  until  recent  times  able  to  avoid  involvement  in  costly  and 
destructive  foreign  wars  and  to  devote  its  major  energies  to  peaceful  pur- 
suits. However,  progress  in  weapons  development,  the  collapse  of  the 
historic  balance-of -power  system  in  Western  Europe,  and  the  emergence 
of  Communist  Russia,  are  factors  which  are  rapidly  eliminating  the  ad- 
vantage of  virtual  insularity  formerly  enjoyed  by  the  United  States. 

Though  exceeded  in  size  by  the  U.S.S.R.,  China,  Canada,  and  Brazil, 
the  United  States  has  a  more  favorable  physical  environment  than  any  of 
these  countries.  Virtually  all  of  the  United  States  falls  into  Ellsworth 
Huntington's  "very  high  energy"  zone  where  the  climate  is  believed  to  be 
most  invigorating  for  human  endeavor.  The  proportion  of  productive  land 
area  is  much  greater  in  the  United  States  than,  for  example,  in  the  U.S.S.R. 
or  Canada  where  large  regions  lie  in  the  Arctic  Zone,  or  in  Brazil,  with  its 
vast  tropical  rain  forest  of  limited  economic  value.  The  great  size  of  the 
United  States,  its  distribution  over  wide  latitudes,  and  the  modifying  in- 
fluence of  mountains  and  two  oceans  produce  a  wide  variety  of  climates 

1  L.  D.  Stamp  and  L.  S.  Suggate,  eds.,  Geography  For  Today,  Book  3,  "North 
America  and  Asia,"  4th  ed.  (London,  1954),  p.  119. 


THE  UNITED  STATES  AND  CANADA  569 

and  a  corresponding  diversity  of  crops.  "Rocks  of  almost  every  geological 
age  furnish  in  abundance  almost  every  kind  of  mineral.  .  .  ."  2  Size  has 
contributed  to  the  economic  growth  of  the  United  States  in  another  im- 
portant respect.  Products  move  freely  without  interference  of  tariff  bar- 
riers over  a  market  area  of  3  million  square  miles  with  more  than  160 
million  consumers.  As  a  result  the  United  States  enjoys  the  large  economic- 
benefits  to  be  derived  from  a  high  degree  of  regional  specialization  and 
the  economies  of  large-scale  production.  Free  Europe,  by  contrast,  with 
an  area  smaller  than  the  United  States  and  a  population  of  over  300  mil- 
lion, comprises  seventeen  sovereign  states  administering  fourteen  separate 
tariff  systems  each  operating  to  prevent  the  most  efficient  utilization  of  the 
area's  resources.  A  wide  domestic  market  also  has  reduced  the  dependence 
of  the  United  States  on  foreign  trade,  thus  making  it  less  vulnerable  to 
foreign  economic  developments. 

Four  main  physical  divisions  may  be  distinguished  in  the  United  States. 
Virtually  all  of  the  western  part  of  the  country,  except  for  a  narrow  strip 
of  lowland  along  the  Pacific  Coast,  comprises  the  western  highlands. 
These  extend  from  Mexico  into  Canada  and  consist  of  a  series  of  plateaus 
and  hills  interspersed  with  high  mountains.  The  plateaus  are  cut  off  from 
rain-bearing  winds  from  the  Pacific  by  high  mountains  so  that  the  region 
is  generally  dry.  While  large  irrigation  projects  have  made  farming  prac- 
tical in  some  of  the  interior  basins,  agriculture  is  generally  limited  to  the 
lowlands  and  valleys  near  the  coast.  Elsewhere  in  this  region,  despite  the 
growth  of  manufactures  in  recent  years,  stock  raising,  forestry,  and  min- 
ing are  of  major  importance.  The  latter  two  activities  have  been  favored 
by  an  abundance  of  mineral  and  forestry  resources  and  large  low-cost 
hydro-electric  power  development. 

Next  come  the  great  interior  plains  or  lowlands.  A  continuation  of  the 
Canadian  prairie  provinces,  they  extend  to  the  Gulf  of  Mexico  and  have  a 
maximum  breadth  of  1500  miles.  Within  this  zone,  the  upper  Mississippi 
Valley  and  the  Great  Lakes  region  constitute  the  heart  of  the  North 
American  continent.  Fertile  alluvial  and  glacial  soils,  an  abundance  of 
coal,  metals,  and  water  power,  and  a  well-developed  water  and  railway 
network  have  made  this  the  most  important  agricultural  and  industrial 
region  in  the  United  States. 

East  of  the  great  plains  are  the  eastern  highlands  or  Appalachians. 
xMuch  lower  in  elevation  than  the  western  highlands,  the  Appalachians 
roughly  parallel  the  Atlantic  Coast,  extending  from  Maine  to  Alabama. 
The  northern  Appalachians  contain  the  richest  coalfields  in  the  United 

2  Ibid.,  p.  164. 


570       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

States  and  account  for  almost  three-quarters  of  the  total  output.  These 
coalfields  form  the  basis  of  the  heavy  industry  complex  in  the  northeastern 
and  north-central  part  of  the  United  States. 

The  fourth  major  physical  division  is  the  coastal  plain  bordering  the 
Gulf  of  Mexico  and  the  Atlantic  coast,  This  region  is  broad  at  the  Gulf 
and  narrows  toward  the  north  where  the  Appalachians  reach  almost  to 
the  sea.  First  settled  by  the  original  colonists,  parts  of  the  eastern  lowlands 
have  remained  the  most  highly  developed  and  densely  populated  regions 
in  the  United  States. 

While  the  river  system  played  an  important  role  in  the  development  of 
the  United  States  up  through  the  first  half  of  the  nineteenth  century,  its 
significance  was  reduced  by  the  fact  that  the  principal  rivers  flow  in  the 
opposite  direction  to  the  main  stream  of  commerce,  which  is  east  and  west. 
Thus  the  Mississippi  system,  largest  in  the  United  States  and  third  largest 
in  the  world  and  navigable  for  thousands  of  miles,  flows  north  and  south 
entering  the  Atlantic  through  the  Gulf  of  Mexico.  Rivers  entering  the 
Atlantic  between  the  St.  Lawrence  River  and  the  Gulf  are  small  and  of 
limited  direct  value  to  navigation.  However,  they  form  estuaries  and  har- 
bors in  their  lower  courses  endowing  the  Atlantic  coast  with  excellent  sea- 
ports like  New  York  and  Baltimore.  The  one  east-west  water  route  of  major 
significance  is  the  St.  Lawrence-Great  Lakes  system  which  connects  the 
heart  of  North  America  with  the  Atlantic  Ocean.  This  system  will  become 
of  increasing  importance  with  the  completion  of  the  St.  Lawrence  Seaway 
described  elsewhere  in  this  chapter. 

People.  The  population  of  the  United  States  as  reported  by  the  1950 
census  numbered  150.7  million.  The  United  States  is  not  considered  to  be 
overpopulated  in  the  sense  that  the  pressure  of  numbers  on  natural  re- 
sources is  an  obstacle  to  continued  economic  expansion.  The  population 
is  increasing  at  a  rapid  rate  and  by  April  1,  1956  had  reached  an  esti- 
mated 167.4  million.  Between  1948  and  1952  the  annual  rate  of  increase 
was  1.76  per  cent  as  compared  with  0.9  per  cent  for  Free  Europe  and  1.5 
to  1.7  per  cent  for  the  Soviet  Union.3  The  present  rapid  growth  of  popu- 
lation is  due  almost  entirely  to  natural  increases.  During  the  decade  1940 
to  1950  immigration  accounted  for  less  than  5  per  cent  of  the  growth  in 
population  and  in  the  previous  decade  for  less  than  one  per  cent.  This  is 
in  sharp  contrast  with  the  period  1850  to  1910  when  immigrants  accounted 
for  anywhere  from  27  per  cent  to  55  per  cent  of  the  increase  in  population 

3  Joint  Committee  on  The  Economic  Report,  Trends  Toward  Economic  Growth,  A 
Comparison  of  Western  Powers  and  The  Soviet  Bloc  (Washington,  D.  C,  1955),  p.  6. 


THE  UNITED  STATES  AND  CANADA  571 

in  a  single  decade.4  Between  1820  and  1951  more  than  40  million  immi- 
grants entered  the  United  States,  of  whom  an  estimated  30  million  re- 
mained. The  abandonment  of  a  liberal  immigration  policy  after  World 
War  I  sharply  reduced  the  influx  of  immigrants.  In  1953  net  immigration 
of  less  than  150,000  was  below  the  authorized  quota  level. 

The  proportion  of  the  total  population  which  the  foreign-born  white 
population  represents  has  fallen  progressively  since  the  end  of  the  nine- 
teenth century.  In  1950  foreign-born  whites  were  7  per  cent  of  the  total 
population  as  compared  with  almost  15  per  cent  in  1890.  Negroes,  de- 
scendants of  the  original  slaves,  accounted  for  10  per  cent  of  the  total 
population  in  1950  as  compared  with  almost  16  per  cent  a  century  earlier. 
Other  races  including  North  American  Indians  represented  only  about 
one-half  of  one  per  cent  of  the  total. 

Average  population  density  in  1950  was  50.7  persons  per  square  mile. 
Greatest  densities  are  in  the  industrialized  and  urbanized  northern  and 
eastern  states.  The  New  England,  Middle  Atlantic,  and  East  North-Cen- 
tral states  had  an  average  population  density  of  178  per  square  mile  in 
1950.  These  fifteen  states  with  15  per  cent  of  the  land  area  of  the  United 
States  had  more  than  half  the  total  population.  Most  thinly-populated  are 
the  Mountain  and  West  North-Central  states  with  average  densities  of 
5.9  and  27.5  persons  per  square  mile  respectively.5  Rational  considerations 
such  as  economic  opportunities,  cultural  advantages,  and  climate  have 
had  an  important  effect  on  the  distribution  of  population.  However,  the 
prewar  National  Resources  Committee  study  showed  that  "historical  acci- 
dent and  differential  reproduction  rates  have  played  a  far  larger  part  in 
determining  population  distribution  in  this  country  than  is  generally  sup- 
posed. The  sheer  size  of  our  land  area,  its  geographical  diversity,  and  the 
variety  of  cultural  patterns  controlling  our  interests  and  attitudes  have 
served  to  intensify  the  force  of  these  irrational  factors."  6 

The  population  of  the  United  States  shows  a  high  degree  of  mobility.7 
The  two  main  channels  of  movement  have  been  ( 1 )  westward  and  ( 2 ) 
away  from  the  farms  to  urban  industrial  centers  ( Fig.  18-1 ).  A  measure  of 
the  extent  of  the  westward  movement  is  indicated  by  the  fact  that  be- 
tween 1790  and  1950  the  center  of  population  of  the  United  States  moved 

4  J.  F.  Dewhurst  and  associates,  America's  Needs  and  Resources  (New  York,  1955), 
p.  51. 

5  Ibid.,  p.  69. 

6  U.S.  Government  Printing  Office,  The  Problems  of  a  Changing  Population  (New 
York,  1938),  p.  37. 

7  See  pp.  168,  169, 


572        THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 


ILLINOIS 


Springfield  jlndianapolis 

195°*    >***    *   *     * 
I        Frankfort  • 


\         SI         ^ 

New  York^i 

WPhiladelphi 

shingtonT<<y.  J « 

1 


J^  KENTUCKY  \VIRGINIA3  •       "S  I  / 

//\.y^  VIRGINIA     Richmond 

s 


N.C. 


"» 


s.c. 


JRF 


Fig.  18-1.  The  Westward  Course  of  the  United  States  as  Shown  in  the  Ten-year  Shift 

of  the  Population  Center,  1790-1950. 

from  its  original  location  east  of  Baltimore  to  a  point  near  Olney,  Illinois, 
686  miles  west  and  30  miles  south.  This  westward  movement  is  a  continu- 
ing one.  Between  1940  and  1950  the  center  of  population  moved  a  distance 
of  42  miles  west  and  7.6  miles  south.  Greatest  relative  growth  has  occurred 
in  the  Pacific  states  and  Mountain  states  which  in  1950  accounted  for  13 
per  cent  of  the  total  population  as  compared  with  5.4  per  pent  in  1900.  Be- 
tween 1940  and  1950  the  population  of  the  Pacific  states  increased  48.8 
per  cent  and  the  mountain  states  22.3  per  cent  as  compared  with  the 
national  average  of  14.3  per  cent.  Increasing  economic  opportunities  re- 
sulting from  the  wartime  expansion  of  industry  and  the  postwar  boom 
have  added  impetus  to  the  movement  of  population  to  the  Pacific  states 
in  the  past  decade,  especially  to  California. 

Like  the  westward  movement  of  population,  the  movement  of  persons 
from  the  farm  and  rural  areas  to  urban  centers  has  been  going  on  since 
Independence.  In  1790  only  about  5  per  cent  of  the  population  of  the 
United  States  was  classified  as  urban.  By  1950  almost  58  per  cent  of  the 
population  was  urban  (living  in  communities  of  2500  persons  or  more).8 
Between  1890  and  1950  the  proportion  of  the  population  living  in  cities 
of  100,000  or  more  rose  from  15.4  per  cent  to  29.3  per  cent.  This  progres- 
sive decline  in  the  rural  population  reflects  the  great  increase  in  the  rela- 

8  W.  S.  and  E.  S.  Woytinsky,  World  Population  and  Production  (New  York,  1953), 
p.  124. 


THE  UNITED  STATES  AND  CANADA  573 

tive  importance  of  industrial  activity  over  the  past  century  or  more,  and 
the  reduced  relative  importance  of  agriculture. 


RESOURCES 

The  United  States  has  a  rich  and  varied  natural  resource  base  (Fig. 
18-2 ) .  In  contrast  with  most  other  developed  nations,  these  resources  were 
adequate  until  quite  recently  to  satisfy  the  bulk  of  this  country's  food  and 
industrial  raw  material  needs  and  to  provide  a  sizeable  surplus  for  export. 
Thus  in  1900  the  United  States  produced  a  15  per  cent  surplus  of  materials 
other  than  food  and  gold.9  However,  by  the  decade  of  the  forties  this  sur- 
plus had  become  a  deficit  as  a  result  of  the  unsatiable  and  rapidly-rising 
demands  of  American  industry.  According  to  the  report  of  the  President's 
Materials  Policy  Commission  "there  is  scarcely  a  metal  or  a  mineral  fuel 
of  which  the  quantity  used  in  the  United  States  since  the  outbreak  of  the 
First  World  War  did  not  exceed  the  total  used  throughout  the  world  in 
all  the  centuries  preceding."  10  With  less  than  10  per  cent  of  the  popula- 
tion of  the  Free  World,  the  United  States  consumes  almost  half  the 
volume  of  materials  produced.  Thus  we  find  that  by  1950  the  United 
States  had  a  9  per  cent  materials  production  deficit  (excluding  food  and 
gold)  and  the  projected  possible  deficit  for  1975  is  estimated  at  20  per 
cent.  This  trend  accounts  in  considerable  measure  for  the  growing  United 
States  interest  in  developing  new  foreign  sources  of  supply  for  minerals 
and  fuels  and  explains  why  the  bulk  of  United  States  overseas  investment 
since  the  war  has  been  going  into  mineral  development. 

Agricultural  Land.  Agriculture  is  the  major  exception  in  the  United 
States  changing  materials  picture.  This  country's  agricultural  resource 
base  currently  yields  all  major  food  and  agricultural  raw  material  re- 
quirements except  tropical  products  like  rubber,  coffee,  and  sugar,  and 
in  addition  provides  sizeable  surpluses  for  export.  According  to  the  Presi- 
dent's Materials  Policy  Commission,  the  United  States  should  have  no 
great  difficulty  in  meeting  the  projected  38  per  cent  increase  in  consump- 
tion of  agricultural  products  by  1975  on  the  basis  of  existing  land-use  now 
in  farms.  "This  can  be  done  by  improving  or  upgrading  the  use  of  much 
land  now  in  farms  and  by  bringing  in  new  land  only  to  offset  any  farm 
acres  that  will  be  taken  out  for  urban  and  other  uses."  1X 

According  to  the  1950  Census,  the  cropland  of  the  United  States  totaled 

9  The  President's  Materials  Policy  Commission,  Resources  for  Freedom,  Vol.  1, 
Foundations  for  Growth  and  Security  (Washington,  D.  C,  June,  1952),  p.  2. 

10  Ibid.,  p.  3. 

11  Ibid.,  Vol.  5,  Selected  Reports  to  the  Commission,  p.  70. 


CS 

0 

u 

y 

3 

n 

CA 

a 

ts 

ca 

S 

a 

0 

■- 

ca 

.a 

- 

-n 

- 

3; 

o\ 

4-i 

CJ 

cj 

•  c* 

CJ 

03 

X 

9) 

cs  in 


T3 

CE 

a 

•** 

x 

ca 

y * 

M 

-H 

na 

a 

ca 

Gfl 

_^ 

a 

0 

c 

— 

ca 

u 

S 

= 

3 

u 

0 

a 

- 

O  ft 


■* 


-    u 


a 

a 

1  (J 

— 

a 

"~ 

ca 

, » 

M 

o 

' — ' 

CJ 

•- 

.« 

a 

c 

eg 

o 

a 

tf 

M 

1 

— 

J 

ca 

B 

a 

S 

1* 

", 

(J 

ca 

c 

P3 

E 

ca 

*-* 

u 

-C 

eg 

,fi 

s 

3 

«*1 

1 

■S} 

c 

•  «\ 

cm 

eg 

3 
< 

u 

ca 

— 

. 

_= 

CI 

sc 

a 

ea 

— i 

1 

< 

U 

- — 

574 


THE  UNITED  STATES  AND  CANADA  575 

409  million  acres  or  somewhat  more  than  two  and  a  half  acres  per  person. 
While  this  is  considerably  less  than  the  555.9  million  acres  estimated  for 
the  U.S.S.R.  by  the  Food  and  Agriculture  Organization  of  the  United 
Nations,  the  difference  may  be  more  apparent  than  real.  Severe  climate 
and  inferior  soils  in  a  number  of  regions  operate  to  materially  reduce  the 
productivity  of  Russian  croplands.  Colin  Clark  has  estimated  that  the 
U.S.S.R.  has  only  about  70  per  cent  of  the  "standard  farmland"  of  the 
United  States. 

Forests.  One-third  of  this  country's  land  area  or  622  million  acres  is  in 
forest  land.  However,  of  this  area  only  460  million  acres  is  suitable  for 
the  growing  of  commercial  timber.  Despite  this  large  acreage  the  United 
States  has  shifted  from  an  exporter  to  an  importer  of  lumber,  largely 
because  of  the  failure  to  build  up  productive  stock.  However,  it  is  esti- 
mated that  forest  land  presently  available  would  be  ample  to  cover 
requirements  under  a  proper  forestry  management  program.12  A  recent 
report  of  the  United  States  Forest  Service  shows  that  in  1955,  the  United 
States  for  the  first  time  in  its  history  was  growing  more  timber  than  was 
being  removed  by  cutting  or  destruction.13 

Minerals.  Despite  the  substantial  inroads  made  into  reserves  and  the 
growing  importance  of  mineral  imports  the  United  States  still  meets  the 
bulk  of  its  requirements  from  domestic  sources.  Thus  in  1950,  United 
States  mineral  production,  excluding  gold,  was  approximately  90  per  cent 
of  apparent  consumption.  Reserves  of  many  of  the  important  minerals 
are  still  abundant.  Table  18-1,  prepared  by  the  President's  Materials 
Policy  Commission,  lists  the  major  industrial  minerals  in  three  groups 
according  to  the  adequacy  of  known  United  States'  reserves.  Metals 
shown  as  deficient  in  reserves  in  relation  to  expected  future  needs  are 
further  broken  down  according  to  prospects  for  improving  supplies  by 
discovery  of  new  deposits,  beneficiation  of  low-grade  ores,  and  replace- 
ment by  synthetics  or  substitutes. 

The  Commission's  study  indicates  that  the  possibilities  of  increasing 
reserves  in  most  of  the  deficient  categories  are  still  considerable.  It  points 
out  that  "geologists  agree  that  the  United  States  still  possesses  vast  hidden 
mineral  resources."  14  The  principal  unknown  factor  is  the  cost  of  exploit- 
ing these  resources.  Technological  progress  has  been  important  in  the 
past  in  permitting  the  use  of  lower-grade  reserves  and  there  is  every 
reason  why  this  should  be  so  in  the  future.  Furthermore,  it  should  be 

12  Ibid.,  p.  37. 

13  As  reported  in  the  Wall  Street  Journal,  October  27,  1955. 

14  Ibid.,  Vol.  5,  p.  27. 


576       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

TABLE  18-1 
Domestic  Supply  Position  of  Selected  Mineral  Materials  * 

1.    Known  Economic  Reserves  Adequate  For  Well  Over  25  Years 


Magnesium 

Coal 

Potash 

Molybdenum 

Phosphate 

Lime 

Salt 

Sand 

Clay 
Borax 

Gypsum 
Bauxite 

Feldspar 

2.    Known  Economic  Reserves  Inadequate 

a.    Discoveries  geologically  likely  though  not 

necessarily  adequate 

Copper 
Zinc 

Lead 
Uranium 

Vanadium 

Tungsten 

Antimony 
Natural  Gas 

Petroleum 
Sulfur 

b.    Beneficiation  progress  expected: 

Iron 

Aluminum 

Titanium 

Beryllium 

Thorium 

Oil  from  Shale 

Fluorine 

Graphite 

c.    Synthesis  progress  expected: 

Oil  from  Coal 

Gas  from  Oil 

3.    Little  or  No  Known  Economic  Reserves,  Significant  Discoveries  Not  Expected 

a.  Beneficiation   progress   expected: 

Manganese 

b.  Synthesis  progress  expected: 

Industrial  Diamonds  Quartz  Crystals 

Sheet  Mica  Asbestos 

c.  Significant  beneficiation  or  synthesis  not  expected: 

Chromium  Nickel 

Tin  Cobalt 

Platinum  Mercury 

*  The  President's  Materials  Policy  Commission,  Vol.   1,  Foundations  for  Growth  and  Security  (Washing- 
ton, D.  C,  June,  1952),  Resources  for  Freedom,  p.  26. 

pointed  out  that  even  if  such  reserves  should  prove  to  be  relatively  high 
cost,  the  resultant  drain  on  the  United  States  economy  is  not  likely  to  be 
excessive.  In  1950,  the  total  value  of  all  metals  consumed  in  the  United 
States  was  roughly  $2  billion  or  less  than  one  per  cent  of  the  Gross  Na- 
tional Product.  At  present  the  United  States  employs  only  4.5  per  cent 
of  its  total  manpower  to  produce  crude  materials  other  than  food.15  Tech- 

15  Op.  cit.,  p.  69. 


THE  UNITED  STATES  AND  CANADA  577 

nological  developments  in  beneficiation  and  synthesis  promise  to  increase 
the  reserves  of  a  number  of  important  minerals  at  relatively  moderate 
cost  increases.  Thus  while  the  United  States  may  exhaust  its  reserves  of 
high-grade,  low-cost  iron  ore  of  the  Lake  Superior  region  in  the  next 
twenty-five  years,  it  has  huge  reserves  of  taconite  with  25  to  35  per  cent 
iron  ore  content.  On  the  basis  of  methods  of  concentration  now  being 
developed,  it  is  estimated  that  the  use  of  these  ores  would  raise  the  cost 
of  pig  iron  only  about  5  per  cent.16  Proved  recoverable  oil  reserves  in  the 
United  States  at  the  end  of  1954  of  29.6  billion  barrels  represented  only 
about  eleven  years'  consumption  at  the  then  prevailing  rate,  and  still  un- 
discovered reserves  were  estimated  to  amount  to  only  about  35.9  billion 
barrels.  However,  it  is  estimated  that  500  billion  barrels  could  be  pro- 
duced, at  higher  cost  of  course,  from  synthetic  shale  deposits.  Large-scale 
oil  production  from  huge  coal  reserves  is  also  possible. 

This  is  not  to  suggest  that  the  United  States  has  no  reason  to  be  con- 
cerned about  its  future  resource  position.  The  problem  of  increasing 
reserves  is  more  than  a  matter  of  higher  costs.  Market  forces  alone  can- 
not always  be  depended  upon  to  bring  about  the  required  expansion. 
Long-range  planning  and  various  measures  requiring  direct  government 
intervention  may  be  necessary.  Minerals  are  finite  and  exhaustible  re- 
sources. Even  if  current  estimates  of  United  States'  reserves  are  on  the 
low  side,  serious  deficiencies  could  develop,  if  not  in  twenty-five  years, 
then  in  fifty  years,  if  proper  steps  are  not  taken  now.  Fifty  years  is  not  a 
long  time  in  the  life-span  of  a  nation. 

The  United  States  has  always  been  deficient  in  such  important  minerals 
as  chromite,  cobalt,  industrial  diamonds,  nickel,  and  manganese.  As 
shown  in  Table  18-2  domestic  production  of  these  minerals  in  1949  was 
10  per  cent  or  less  of  domestic  consumption.  The  same  table  also  shows 
the  considerable  decline  that  has  occurred  since  1935  to  1939  in  this 
country's  relative  self-sufficiency  in  copper,  lead,  and  zinc.  The  figures  in 
Table  18-2  need  to  be  interpreted  with  caution  regarding  what  they  imply 
for  the  strategic  security  of  the  United  States.  As  noted  above,  imports 
in  some  cases  reflect  cost  considerations  rather  than  absolute  shortages. 
Where  serious  deficiencies  exist  as  in  the  case  of  minerals  like  nickel  and 
tin,  the  building  up  of  strategic  stockpiles  affords  considerable  insurance 
against  serious  wartime  deficiencies.  Furthermore,  in  a  national  emer- 
gency substantial  cutbacks  in  nonessential  consumption  can  be  made. 
Then,  of  course,  there  is  a  wide  range  of  possibilities  in  the  area  of  con- 

16  The  President's,  Materials  Policy  Commission,  op.  cit.,  Vol.  2,  The  Outlook  for 
Key  Commodities,  p.  5. 


578       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

servation,  standardization,  and  substitution.  Finally,  it  should  be  noted 
that  most  of  the  imported  minerals  come  from  Western  Hemisphere 
sources  which  greatly  reduces  the  threat  of  enemy  takeover  and  the  prob- 
lem of  maintaining  lines  of  communication.  For  these  reasons,  even 
though  being  cut  off  from  foreign  sources  of  supply  in  wartime  would 
present  difficult  problems  of  adjustment  for  the  United  States,  the  over-all 
effect  on  its  war  effort  would  be  very  minor. 

TABLE  18-2 
Relative  Self-Sufficiency  of  U.  S.  in  Minerals,   1935-39  and  1949  * 


SELF-SUFFICIENCY : 

RATIO  OF  DOMESTIC 

MINERAL 

PRODUCTION 

TO  DOMESTIC  CONSUMPTION 
(  PER  CENT  ) 

1935-1939 

1949 

Antimony 

Asbestos  (long  fiber) 

Chromite 

12 
5 

1 

24 
8 

a 

Coal: 

Anthracite 

102 

113 

Bituminous  and  Lignite 

103 

98 

Cobalt 

11 

Copper 

Diamonds  ( Industrial ) 

Iron  Ore 

107 

0 

94 

70 

0 

95 

Lead 

90 

69 

Magnesium 

160 

97 

Manganese 

6 

9 

Mercury 
Molybdenum 

Nickel 

67 

294 
2 

25 

113 

1 

Petroleum  Crude 

109 

94 

Phosphate  Rock 
Platinum  Metals 

151 
32 

115 

12 

Potash 

64 

104 

Sulfur 

128 

139 

Tin 

a 

a 

Tungsten 

32 

58 

Zinc 

94 

74 

n  Less  than  0.5  per  cent. 

*  Statistical  Abstract  of  the  United  States,  1952,  p.  693. 

Water  Power.  Water  power  is  much  less  important  as  a  source  of 
energy  in  the  United  States  than  coal,  oil,  or  gas.  In  1950  it  accounted 
for  only  about  five  per  cent  of  this  country's  production  of  commercial 
energy,  as  against  roughly  43  per  cent  for  coal,  32  per  cent  for  oil,  and 
20  per  cent  for  gas.  Although  the  United  States  possesses  only  about  5 
per  cent  of  the  world's  hydraulic  resources,  it  produces  roughly  30  per 
cent  of  all  the  hydro-electric  energy.  Untapped  hydraulic  resources  are 
estimated  at  about  four  times  what  is  presently  being  utilized. 


THE  UNITED  STATES  AND  CANADA 


579 


100 


50 100  150  Mi 

200 


300  Km 


T.  V.  A. 

!    34  MAJOR  DAMS 

'     12  STEAM  GENERATING  PLANTS     V 
10,  000  MILES  OF  POWERLINES 
8,000,000  KILOWATT  CAPACITY 

} 


mi 


Fig.  18-3.  Regional  Extent  of  TVA  Activity. 

Despite  the  relatively  minor  position  of  hydro-electric  power  in  the 
total  energy  picture,  it  has  been  an  important  factor  in  the  development 
of  certain  regions  of  the  United  States,  especially  where  combined  with 
irrigation  and  flood  control.  The  most  notable  of  such  multiple  purpose 
projects  is  the  government-financed  Tennessee  Valley  Authority,17  one  of 
the  world's  major  engineering  projects  (Fig.  18-3).  Here  power  develop- 
ment was  secondary  to  the  primary  purpose  of  creating  a  nine-foot  chan- 
nel for  navigation  from  Knoxville  to  the  mouth  of  the  Tennessee  River, 
and  for  the  prevention  of  floods.  Other  objectives  included  erosion  control, 
reforestation,  and  rural  rehabilitation.  TVA  has  had  a  major  impact  on  the 
economy  of  the  Tennessee  Valley.  The  well-being  of  the  farm  population 
has  been  greatly  improved  and  a  major  impetus  was  given  to  the  develop- 
ment of  manufactures.  Other  notable  multi-purpose  schemes  are  the 
Columbia  and  Colorado  River  projects.  Both  have  provided  low-cost 
power  for  industries  in  the  Pacific  Northwest  as  well  as  water  for  the 


17  See  p.  663. 


580       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

irrigation  of  dry  land.  The  Tennessee  Valley  authority  and  other  large 
multi-purpose  projects  have  brought  the  Federal  Government  into  the 
power  business  in  competition  with  private  utilities.  The  resultant  clash 
of  interests  has  had  and  will  continue  to  have  important  political  reper- 
cussions. 

CHARACTERISTICS  OF  THE  ECONOMY 

In  1954  the  United  States  had  a  gross  national  product  of  $360.5  billion, 
as  compared  with  less  than  $200  billion  for  Free  Europe  and  only  about 
$175  billion  for  the  entire  European  Soviet  bloc.  Per  capita  income  of 
almost  $2300  per  annum  was  four  times  the  Western  European  average 
and  four  and  a  half  times  that  of  the  Soviet  Union.  Of  the  total  United 
States  gross  national  product  two-thirds  represented  personal  consump- 
tion expenditures.  All  major  indicators  of  economic  potential  point  to  the 
overwhelming  economic  strength  of  the  United  States  in  relation  to  other 
countries.  The  United  States  accounts  for  almost  40  per  cent  of  the 
world's  output  of  manufactures.  It  is  the  largest  single  producer  of  agri- 
cultural products  and  minerals;  it  produces  40  per  cent  of  all  commercial 
energy.  Its  production  of  crude  steel  is  only  moderately  less  than  that  of 
Western  Europe  and  the  Soviet  Bloc  combined. 

During  the  first  hundred  years  of  its  history  the  United  States  was 
primarily  an  agricultural  economy.  The  availability  of  extensive  and  rich 
agricultural  lands  was  a  highly  dynamic  factor  in  the  expansion  of  the 
economy  during  this  period.  It  attracted  much  needed  immigration.  Agri- 
culture provided  the  surplus  required  to  feed  an  increasing  urban 
industrial  population  and  was  a  primary  source  of  savings  and  investment. 
Despite  the  rapid  growth  of  industry,  agriculture  still  contributed  50  per 
cent  more  to  national  income  than  manufacturing  in  the  decade  1869  to 
1879  (see  Table  18-3  below). 

It  was  not  until  1890  that  manufacturing  surpassed  agriculture  as  the 
principal  source  of  income.  By  1953,  manufacturing  was  almost  six  times 
as  important  as  agriculture.  The  tall  in  the  relative  contribution  of  agricul- 
ture to  total  output  has  been  accompanied  by  a  still  sharper  decline  in 
the  proportion  of  the  gainfully  employed  persons  engaged  in  agricultural 
pursuits.  In  1870  more  than  50  per  cent  of  the  total  United  States'  labor 
force  was  in  agriculture.  By  1953  the  proportion  had  declined  to  less  than 
10  per  cent.  The  other  most  striking  change  in  the  composition  of  the 
country's  national  income  has  been  the  increasing  contribution  of  govern- 
ment. This  is  a  result  of  a  long-run  trend  reflecting  the  growing  complexity 
of  economic  and  social  life  requiring  increasing  government  respon- 
sibilities. 


THE  UNITED  STATES  AND  CANADA  581 

Total  output  in  the  United  States  has  been  increasing  at  a  rapid  rate. 
Between  1938  and  1953  gross  national  product  in  constant  prices  rose 
roughly  120  per  cent  as  against  an  increase  of  about  40  per  cent  for  Free 
Europe  and  62  per  cent  for  the  Soviet  Union.18  However,  these  differ- 
ences reflect  to  an  important  degree  the  fact  that  the  United  States  was 
spared  the  destructive  effects  of  World  War  II.  Thus  between  1948  and 
1953  the  increase  in  United  States  production  was  only  27  per  cent  as 
against  21  per  cent  for  Free  Europe.  In  the  same  period  United  States 
output  increased  only  about  two-thirds  as  rapidly  as  that  of  the  U.S.S.R. 

TABLE  18-3 

National  Income  by  Major  Industrial  Divisions 

1953  and  1869-1879  * 

( Percentage  Distribution ) 


industry  1953 


1869-1879 

( AVERAGE ) 


Agriculture,  forestry  and  fishing 

5.5 

20.5 

Mining 

1.8 

1.8 

Construction 

4.9 

5.3 

Manufacturing 

32.0 

13.9 

Wholesale  and  retail  trade 

17.2 

15.7 

Finance,  insurance,  real  estate,  et 

cetera 

9.3 

11.7 

Transportation  and  other  public  utilities 

8.5 

11.9 

Services 

9.4 

14.7 

Government 

11.4 

4.4 

*  Data  for  1953  taken  from  United  States  Department  of  Commerce,  Survey  of  Current  Business, 
February.  1955,  and  for  1869-79  from  United  States  Department  of  Commerce,  Historical  Statistics  of 
the  United  States  1789-1945  (Washington,  D.  C,  1945),  p.  13. 

The  economic  supremacy  of  the  United  States  reflects  the  relatively 
high  productivity  of  American  industry  and  agriculture.  Productivity  in 
the  sense  of  output  per  man-hour  was  substantially  higher  in  the  United 
States  before  the  war  than  in  Europe  as  a  whole,  and  this  lead  has  been 
extended  in  the  postwar  years.19  Again  much  of  the  difference  since  the 
war  reflects  the  damage  and  dislocation  caused  by  the  war  to  European 
industry  and  agriculture.  Since  the  war  man-hour  productivity  in  the 
United  States  has  been  increasing  at  a  rate  of  3.5  per  cent  per  year. 
Currently,  this  means  that  the  United  States  is  adding  $13  billion  an- 
nually to  its  output  of  goods  and  services.  A  study  of  31  industries  for 
the  period  1935  to  1939  found  average  output  per  man-hour  in  the  United 
States  to  be  approximately  2.8  greater  than  in  the  United  Kingdom  where 

18  Joint  Committee  On  The  Economic  Report,  op.  cit.,  p.  2. 

19  Organization  For  European  Economic  Co-operation,  The  Report  of  the  OEEC, 
Vol.  1  (March,  1955),  p.  55 


582       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

it  was  roughly  the  same  as  in  Germany  and  Sweden.20  Output  per  man- 
hour  in  agriculture  in  the  United  States  increased  by  approximately  two- 
thirds  between  1935-39  and  1951.  The  increase  for  Western  Europe  as  a 
whole  in  the  same  period  was  probably  about  one-fifth. 

Favorable  geographical  factors  alone,  including  resources  and  climate, 
do  not  explain  the  high  output  per  capita  in  the  United  States.  Environ- 
mental factors  clearly  affect  productivity  but  their  significance  tends  to 
decline  as  a  country  becomes  more  highly  developed.  Rich  resources  are 
of  particular  importance  during  the  earlier  stages  of  a  country's  economic 
growth  because  of  the  strong  attraction  they  can  exert  on  capital  and 
labor.  The  discovery  of  gold  in  California  is  an  excellent  example,  as  is 
petroleum  development  in  Texas.  Subsequently,  such  factors  as  tech- 
nology, organization,  management,  worker  skills,  incentives,  and  the  like 
tend  to  overshadow  resources  in  importance.  More  than  anything  else 
it  is  probable  that  the  high  productivity  of  the  United  States  results  from 
the  efficiency  of  the  methods  it  has  developed  to  exploit  its  natural  re- 
sources rather  than  from  the  relative  abundance  of  these  resources  them- 
selves. Of  particular  importance  has  been  the  substitution  of  mechanical 
energy  for  human  energy.  This  explains  why  per  capita  consumption  of 
commercial  energy  in  the  United  States  of  7.51  metric  tons  per  year  coal 
equivalent  is  the  highest  in  the  world.  Indirectly  the  abundance  of  natural 
resources  in  the  United  States,  particularly  agricultural  land,  was  an  im- 
portant factor  in  the  substitution  of  mechanical  labor  for  human  labor. 
Free  land  competed  with  industry  for  labor  during  most  of  the  nineteenth 
century,  thereby  tending  to  force  wages  up.  There  was  thus  a  consider- 
able incentive  for  industry  to  economize  in  the  use  of  labor  and  to  sub- 
stitute machinery  wherever  possible. 

MANUFACTURES 

United  States  industry  is  both  extensive  and  diversified.  In  addition  to 
being  the  world's  leading  manufacturing  nation,  the  United  States  can 
produce  virtually  all  of  its  requirements  of  manufactures  at  costs  equal 
to,  if  not  lower  than,  those  of  foreign  countries.  Production  of  durable 
goods  is  slightly  more  important  than  of  consumer  goods.  The  principal 
industries  in  terms  of  their  contribution  to  national  output  are  machinery 
and  transportation  equipment,  primary  metals  and  fabricated  metal  prod- 
ucts, textile  products  and  apparel,  food  and  kindred  products,  and  chem- 

20  L.  Rostas,  Comparative  Productivity  in  British  and  American  Industry  (London, 

1948). 


THE  UNITED  STATES  AND  CANADA  583 

icals  in  that  order.  Output  in  a  number  of  major  industries  is  quite  highly 
concentrated  in  a  few  firms.  Thus  in  1947,  four  firms  produced  40  per 
cent  or  more  of  the  output  of  the  following  industries: 

1.  Motor  vehicles  and  parts 

2.  Meat  packing 

3.  Steel  works  and  rolling  mills 

4.  Organic  chemicals 

5.  Cigarettes 

6.  Copper  rolling  and  drawing 

7.  Soap  and  glycerin 

While  natural  advantages  have  largely  determined  the  location  of  a 
number  of  important  industries,  other  influences  such  as  historical  factors 
or  the  location  of  consumers  often  have  been  of  equal  if  not  greater  sig- 
nificance. Thus  the  continued  importance  of  industry  in  the  states  border- 
ing the  Atlantic  is  to  an  important  extent  the  result  of  history  (cf.  Fig. 
18-2,  p.  574).  This  region  happened  to  be  settled  first  and  its  industry 
therefore  got  an  earlier  start  than  in  the  rest  of  the  country.  This  is  not  to 
deny  that  the  east  coast  possessed  a  number  of  natural  advantages  by  way 
of  resources,  proximity  to  the  sea  when  ships  were  the  chief  means  of 
communication,  closeness  to  Europe,  and  others.  However,  today,  many  of 
these  advantages  no  longer  exist.  The  development  of  the  automobile  in- 
dustry in  Detroit  came  about  largely  because  this  area  had  been  the  site 
of  the  horse-drawn  carriage  and  wagon  industry.  On  the  other  hand,  the 
location  of  the  steel  industry  together  with  its  supporting  industries  can  be 
attributed  in  large  measure  to  the  presence  of  abundant  coal  and  iron  ore 
fairly  nearby  and  cheap  water  transport  for  the  movement  of  bulky  raw 
materials.  The  development  of  the  aluminum  industry  in  the  Pacific  north- 
west was  largely  determined  by  the  availability  of  cheap  hydro-electric 
power. 

Three  regions,  New  England,  the  Middle  Atlantic  states,  and  the  East 
North  Central  states,  accounted  for  more  than  two-thirds  of  all  United 
States'  manufactures  in  1952.  The  other  principal  manufacturing  regions 
are  the  South  Atlantic  and  the  Pacific  states.  While  the  North  Central  and 
Northeastern  states  dominate  the  industrial  landscape,  important  regional 
shifts  have  been  under  way  for  some  time,  both  westward  and  southward, 
following  the  general  trend  of  population  movements.  The  most  sig- 
nificant changes  have  been  the  increased  relative  importance  of  manu- 
factures in  the  West  South  Central  and  Pacific  states.  This  shift  has  been 
accompanied  by  a  gradual  decline  in  the  relative  importance  of  New 
England  and  the  Middle  Atlantic  states.  Between  1939  and  1952,  the 


584       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

share  of  total  manufactures  for  these  two  regions  declined  from  roughly 
39  per  cent  to  34  per  cent.  The  high  costs  of  labor  and  power  and  the 
absence  of  sufficient  compensating  advantages  have  been  important  fac- 
tors in  this  shift. 

AGRICULTURE 

Despite  its  declining  economic  importance  in  relation  to  manufactures, 
agriculture  has  been  a  major  element  of  strength  in  the  economy  of  the 
United  States.  Twice  in  the  space  of  twenty-five  years  United  States  agri- 
culture was  equal  to  the  task  of  greatly  expanding  output  to  meet  the 
large  wartime  requirements  of  this  country  and  its  allies.  After  both  wars, 
United  States  exports  of  foodstuffs  prevented  widespread  starvation  and 
suffering  in  war-devastated  Europe  and  the  Far  East. 

The  United  States  is  in  the  enviable  position  of  being  the  world's  most 
industrialized  state  and  at  the  same  time  of  being  able  to  easily  meet  all 
of  its  essential  food  and  agricultural  raw  material  needs.  In  addition  the 
United  States  normally  produces  more  agricultural  products  than  it 
consumes  and  therefore  has  a  surplus  for  export.  Agricultural  imports  are 
limited  to  tropical  products  like  rubber,  silk,  tea,  coffee,  spices,  and 
bananas.  Only  the  U.S.S.R.  of  the  other  major  powers  approximates  the 
favorable  agricultural  position  of  the  United  States,  but  as  described  in 
Chapter  15,  it  is  experiencing  increasing  difficulties  in  meeting  its  needs. 

An  outstanding  characteristic  of  United  States'  agriculture  is  its  high 
productivity.  This  was  impressively  demonstrated  during  World  War  II. 
From  1939  to  1944  the  volume  of  agricultural  output  increased  25  per 
cent  with  only  a  6  per  cent  increase  in  crop  acreage  and  an  actual  decline 
in  farm  employment.  Greater  use  of  fertilizers  and  increased  farm  mech- 
anization, combined  with  favorable  weather,  all  contributed  to  bringing 
about  the  increase.  Most  United  States'  farms  are  moderately  large.  In 
1945,  approximately  45  per  cent  of  all  land  in  farms  fell  in  the  50  to  499 
acre  size  category.  Two-thirds  of  the  cropland  harvested  was  by  farms 
in  this  size  range.  Approximately  40  per  cent  of  all  farm  lands  were  in 
farms  of  over  1000  acres.  However,  most  of  this  acreage  was  used  for 
livestock  raising  and  dairying,  since  the  percentage  of  cropland  harvested 
was  less  than  14  per  cent.  Tenancy  is  declining  in  the  United  States.  In 
1930,  42  per  cent  of  all  farms  were  tenant-operated.  By  1945  the  per- 
centage had  declined  to  about  30  per  cent. 

Favored  by  many  different  types  of  climate  the  United  States  produces 
a  wide  variety  of  crops  ranging  from  semi-tropical  products  like  rice, 
sugar  cane,  cotton,  and  oranges,  to  typical  Temperate  Zone  crops  like 


THE  UNITED  STATES  AND  CANADA  585 

wheat,  rye,  and  corn.  Up  until  the  mid-1920's  farm  receipts  from  sales  of 
crops  exceeded  income  from  livestock  and  livestock  products.  By  1950 
receipts  from  livestock  products  were  25  per  cent  higher  than  from  crops. 
This  shift  resulted  in  part  at  least  from  the  rise  in  income  levels  and  the 
resultant  increased  demand  for  high-protein  foods.  The  principal  crops 
were  cotton,  fruits  and  vegetables,  food  grains,  feed  grains,  tobacco,  and 
oil-bearing  crops.  Livestock  represents  more  than  half  of  the  value  of 
livestock  and  livestock  products,  while  dairy  products,  poultry,  and  eggs 
account  for  most  of  the  remainder. 

The  two  principal  agricultural  regions  are  the  West  North  Central  and 
the  East  North  Central  states.  Together  these  two  regions  accounted  for 
approximately  45  per  cent  of  the  value  of  cash  farm  receipts  in  1949. 
These  states  are  the  major  cereal,  livestock,  and  dairying  regions  of  the 
United  States.  Texas,  Mississippi,  and  Arkansas  are  the  major  cotton- 
producing  states.  The  South  Atlantic  states,  primarily  the  Carolinas  and 
Virginia,  produce  two-thirds  of  the  tobacco.  The  Pacific  states,  notably 
California,  produce  the  largest  share  of  fruits,  nuts,  and  vegetables. 

The  productiveness  of  American  agriculture  has  created  difficult  eco- 
nomic and  political  problems  both  here  and  abroad.  Largely  as  a  result 
of  the  inability  of  the  farm  industry  to  adjust  to  the  loss  of  export  markets 
following  the  recovery  of  foreign  agriculture  after  World  War  I  and 
World  War  II,  the  United  States  has  had  a  serious  surplus  problem  for 
three  or  more  decades.  Because  of  the  system  of  Congressional  repre- 
sentation, United  States  farmers  enjoy  much  greater  political  strength 
than  their  numbers  suggest.  Consequently,  strong  political  pressures  have 
been  exerted  to  reduce  the  burden  of  surpluses  on  farm  prices  and 
incomes.  The  result  has  been  a  succession  of  measures,  starting  with  the 
Federal  Farm  Board  of  1929,  to  restrict  output  and  subsidize  farmers. 
Despite  the  expenditure  of  billions  of  dollars  in  farm  aid,  only  limited 
progress  has  been  made  toward  solving  the  problem  of  surpluses,  chiefly 
because  of  the  difficult  political  issues  involved.  In  the  course  of  its 
efforts  to  support  farm  prices,  the  United  States  Government  through  the 
Commodity  Credit  Corporation  has  accumulated  billions  of  dollars  ol 
surplus  farm  products.  Various  measures  have  been  taken  in  recent  years 
to  dispose  of  these  surpluses  abroad  by  sales  at  less  than  world-market 
prices  and  tie-in  arrangements  with  foreign  aid  programs.  While  the 
legislation  governing  such  sales  specifies  that  they  should  not  interfere 
with  the  regular  commercial  exports  of  other  friendly  powers,  this  is 
often  difficult  to  avoid.  A  number  of  countries  like  Canada,  Australia, 
New  Zealand,  and  Argentina  that  depend  heavily  on  agricultural  exports 


586       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

have  expressed  serious  concern  about  the  effects  of  the  surplus  disposal 
programs  on  their  sales  in  foreign  markets. 

TRANSPORTATION 

The  United  States  is  served  by  the  most  extensive  and  probably  one 
of  the  most  efficient  transportation  systems  in  the  world.  The  develop- 
ment of  this  system  closely  paralleled  and  at  the  same  time  was  a  major 
factor  in  promoting  the  growth  of  the  United  States'  economy.  The  vast 
distances  dividing  the  country  were  for  a  time  as  much  or  more  of  a 
hindrance  than  an  asset  to  economic  development.  The  transportation 
system  by  helping  to  bring  about  political  and  economic  unification  laid 
the  basis  for  the  present  high  degree  of  regional  economic  specialization 
which  characterizes  the  United  States. 

The  backbone  of  the  United  States'  internal  transportation  system  is  a 
vast  rail  network  of  roughly  225,000  miles  of  line  which  in  1953  handled 
40  per  cent  of  the  world's  railway  freight  traffic  21  (cf.  Fig.  18-2,  p.  574). 
Important  also  is  the  unexcelled  highway  system  of  more  than  2  million 
miles  of  hard-surfaced  roads  used  by  53  million  passenger  cars  and  trucks, 
about  two-thirds  of  the  Free  World  total.  Of  rapidly  increasing  significance 
are  pipelines  for  the  carriage  of  petroleum  and  natural  gas,  and  air  trans- 
port for  passenger  travel.  While  inland  waterways  have  lost  their  earlier 
pre-eminence  they  are  still  significant  for  the  movement  of  low-cost  bulk 
commodities  and  are  likely  to  become  of  greater  importance  with  the  com- 
pletion of  the  St.  Lawrence  Seaway  described  below.     . 

Natural  as  well  as  technological  factors  have  had  an  important  influ- 
ence on  the  development  of  transport  in  the  United  States.  During  the 
early  period  of  the  country's  history,  highways  were  the  main  arteries 
of  commerce  and  travel.  Lack  of  public  roads  led  to  extensive  construc- 
tion and  use  of  toll  turnpikes  by  private  companies,  particularly  between 
1800  and  1820.  Most  of  the  early  roads  ran  in  a  north  to  south  direction, 
in  part  at  least  because  of  the  difficulties  of  traversing  the  Alleghanies. 
One  of  the  most  notable  exceptions  was  the  famous  Cumberland  Road 
which  followed  the  valley  of  the  Delaware  River  through  the  mountains. 
By  1838  the  Cumberland  Road  extended  from  Cumberland,  Maryland  to 
Vandalia,  Illinois.  After  it  was  opened  to  Wheeling  in  1818,  the  Cumber- 
land Road  became  a  major  thoroughfare  between  the  east  and  the  west. 
Its  economic  significance  is  suggested  by  the  fact  that  the  time  required 
to  travel  from  Baltimore  to  Wheeling  was  reduced  from  eight  to  three 

21  United  Nations,  Statistical  Yearbook,  1954,  p.  289. 


THE  UNITED  STATES  AND  CANADA  587 

days.22  In  general,  highway  transportation  was  very  expensive,  so  that  it 
was  not  economical  to  produce  agricultural  products  or  exploit  mineral 
resources  any  great  distance  from  the  market.  Consequently,  the  rich 
resources  west  of  the  Alleghanies  were  of  limited  economic  value. 

With  the  appearance  of  Robert  Fulton's  steamboat  in  1807  inland  water 
transport  gradually  began  to  assume  increasing  importance.  During  the 
second  quarter  of  the  nineteenth  century  the  Ohio  and  the  Mississippi 
Rivers  were  the  principal  arteries  of  commerce  in  the  Middle  West.  In 
1840,  New  Orleans  was  the  fourth  largest  port  in  the  world.23  The  era  of 
canal-building,  ushered  in  by  the  completion  of  the  Erie  Canal  in  1825, 
gave  a  major  impetus  to  inland  water  transport.  The  Erie  played  an  im- 
portant role  in  the  opening  of  the  West  and  in  establishing  the  com- 
mercial supremacy  of  New  York.  The  Canal  which  extended  from  Ruffalo 
to  Albany  over  a  distance  of  364  miles  provided  a  cheap  all-water  route 
from  the  east  to  the  west,  diverting  considerable  traffic  that  formerly 
went  down  the  Mississippi  to  New  Orleans.  It  gave  New  York  a  great 
advantage  over  Baltimore  and  Philadelphia  in  trade  with  the  west.  The 
financial  success  of  the  Erie  Canal  started  a  veritable  orgy  of  canal-build- 
ing with  highly  unfavorable  financial  consequences  for  a  number  of 
states. 

While  the  railroad  era  began  in  1830,  it  was  not  until  after  the  Civil 
War  that  the  railway  succeeded  the  steamboat  as  the  chief  carrier  of 
domestic  traffic.  At  the  same  time,  with  the  completion  of  the  first  trans- 
continental line  in  1869,  the  shift  in  the  main  flow  of  traffic  from  north 
and  south  to  east  and  west  that  had  begun  with  the  construction  of  the 
Erie  Canal  was  completed.  The  railways  maintained  their  supremacy  un- 
challenged until  World  War  I.  Since  then  heavy  inroads  into  the  railways' 
commanding  position  have  been  made  by  motor  transport,  pipelines,  and 
most  recently  the  airplane. 

Table  18-4  below  clearly  indicates  the  rapid  decline  in  the  relative  im- 
portance of  rail  transport  for  the  movement  of  freight  traffic  during  the 
past  quarter-century,  and  the  rapid  rise  in  the  importance  of  motor  ve- 
hicles and  oil  pipelines.  While  the  volume  of  air  freight  in  1953  totalled 
400  million  ton  miles,  it  was  still  less  than  one-tenth  of  one  per  cent  of  all 
freight  traffic.  The  importance  of  this  traffic  is  greater  than  its  magnitude 
suggests,  however,  because  of  its  speed  and  flexibility.  The  decline  in  rail 
passenger  traffic  has  been  even  more  marked  than  for  railway  freight.  By 
1952  the  railroads  accounted  for  only  50  per  cent  of  all  passenger  traffic 

22  D.  P.  Locklen,  Economics  of  Transportation,  3rd  ed.  (Chicago,  1947),  p.  82. 

23  Ibid.,  p.  72. 


588       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

of  common  carriers  as  compared  with  98  per  cent  in  1915,  while  the  pro- 
portion of  bus  and  airplane  transport  had  increased  to  31  per  cent  and 
18  per  cent  respectively.  However,  passenger  transportation  by  private 
automobiles  of  500  billion  passenger  miles  was  roughly  four  times  greater 
than  that  of  all  common  carriers.  In  addition  to  its  great  impact  on  the 
transportation  use  pattern,  the  phenomenal  growth  in  the  ownership  and 
operation  of  private  automobiles  has  had  a  significant  influence  on  the 
living  habits  of  the  population.  The  automobile  has  been  a  major  factor 
in  the  growing  movement  of  city  workers  into  the  suburbs.  It  has  contrib- 
uted to  the  decentralization  of  industry  and  the  decline  of  the  small  rural 
town. 

TABLE  18-4 

Distribution  of  Intercity  Freight  Traffic 
1926-1953  • 


TRANSPORT  AGENCY 


PER  CENT  DISTRIRUTION 

1926  1950  1953 


Railroads 

Great  Lakes,  rivers,  and  canals 

Trucks 

Oil  Pipelines 

Total: 


77.1 

58.7 

51.7 

15.7 

16.2 

16.9 

2.8 

12.4 

17.4 

4.4 

12.7 

14.0 

100.0 


100.0 


100.0 


*  Data  for  1926  and  1950  were  taken  from  J.  F.  Dewhurst  and  associates,  America's  Needs  and  Re- 
sources (New  York,  1955),  p.  263,  and  for  1953  from  Interstate  Commerce  Commission,  Monthly  Com- 
ment  on  Transportation  Statistics,  October   15,    1954. 


The  rail  system  of  the  United  States  is  very  unequally  distributed.  The 
number  of  lines  and  the  density  of  traffic  is  greatest  in  the  industrial  east 
( see  Fig.  18-2 ) .  In  1950,  states  like  New  Jersey,  Pennsylvania,  and  Illinois 
had  more  than  twenty  miles  of  railway  per  square  mile  of  territory;  at  the 
other  extreme  Nevada  and  Arizona  had  less  than  two  miles.  Similar  differ- 
ences exist  with  respect  to  state  highway  systems.  Unlike  most  countries 
the  United  States  rail  system  is  privately-owned  and  operated. 

Most  of  the  inland  waterway  traffic  moves  on  the  Great  Lakes  and  on 
river  systems  like  that  of  the  Mississippi  and  canals  such  as  the  New  York 
Barge  Canal.  Great  Lakes  traffic  consists  chiefly  of  grain,  iron  ore,  and 
coal.  A  wide  variety  of  cargo  moves  on  the  Mississippi  including  sugar, 
cotton,  and  rice.  While  the  relative  importance  of  inland  water  transport 
has  been  fairly  stable  for  some  time,  the  completion  of  the  St.  Lawrence 
Seaway  is  likely  to  increase  its  role. 

The  Great  Lakes  and  the  St.  Lawrence  River  provide  an  all-water  route 
from  Duluth,  Minnesota,  to  the  Atlantic  Ocean,  a  distance  of  more  than 


THE  UNITED  STATES  AND  CANADA  589 

2,000  miles  (cf.  Fig.  6-11,  p.  166).  However,  deep-draft  ocean  navigation 
cannot  now  go  beyond  Montreal.  The  United  States  and  the  Canadian 
Governments  for  many  years  have  sought  to  develop  the  St.  Lawrence- 
Great  Lakes  route  jointly  so  as  to  enable  deep-draft  ocean-going  vessels 
to  reach  the  Great  Lakes.  Agreement  finally  was  reached  in  1954.  When 
the  project  is  completed  during  1958,  ocean-going  vessels  of  up  to  20,000 
tons  will  be  able  to  sail  into  the  heart  of  the  American  continent.  The 
resultant  reduction  in  transportation  costs  and  increased  water  traffic 
should  bring  widespread  benefits  to  the  mid-west.  Costly  transshipments 
of  grain  from  the  mid-west  to  foreign  destinations  will  be  eliminated.  It  is 
estimated  the  cost  of  shipping  wheat  from  Duluth  to  Montreal  will  be  cut 
by  one-third.24  The  steel  industry,  which  is  70  per  cent  located  on  the 
Great  Lakes,  will  be  able  to  bring  in  ore  directly  by  sea  from  the  rich 
Labrador-Quebec  mines  instead  of  transshipping  it  by  rail  or  to  smaller 
ships  as  at  present.  The  Department  of  Commerce  has  estimated  the  Sea- 
way will  handle  35  million  tons  of  ore  per  annum.  The  Seaway  is  expected 
to  bring  about  a  big  increase  in  general  traffic  between  lake  ports  and  for- 
eign ports.  It  will  be  of  great  strategic  significance  in  wartime  since  it  will 
reduce  the  open  sea  route  from  the  United  States  to  the  United  Kingdom 
by  1,000  miles.  It  has  been  estimated  that  when  the  Seaway  is  completed 
it  will  carry  more  tonnage  than  the  Suez  and  Panama  Canals  combined. 
Clearly  the  Seaway  will  not  be  an  unmixed  blessing.  Eastern  railways  and 
ports  may  be  heavy  losers.25 

Brief  mention  should  be  made  of  coastwise  and  ocean-going  shipping. 
In  1953  the  United  States  had  462  vessels  aggregating  5  million  dead- 
weight tons  actively  engaged  in  coastwise  shipping.  Freight  carried  by 
this  fleet  equalled  about  13  per  cent  of  that  originated  by  the  railroads. 
The  bulk  of  this  traffic  was  petroleum  and  petroleum  products  and  to  a 
much  lesser  extent  coal  and  coke.  The  opening  of  the  Panama  Canal  in 
1914  greatly  stimulated  coastwise  shipping  between  the  east  and  west 
coasts.  The  economies  of  an  all-water  route  from  the  east  coast  to  the  west 
coast  has  made  it  advantageous  to  move  cargo  from  as  far  west  as  Chicago 
to  New  York  or  Philadelphia  for  shipment  to  the  Pacific  Coast  via  the 
Panama  Canal.  In  1953  the  active  United  States  flag  fleet  engaged  in  for- 
eign trade  numbered  629  vessels  aggregating  7,390,000  deadweight  tons. 
American  flag  vessels  in  1953  carried  39  per  cent  of  the  country's  imports 
and  29  per  cent  of  its  exports.  The  total  United  States'  merchant  marine 
is  more  than  double  the  active  fleet.  In  1953,  some  1836  vessels  with  a 

24  The  Economist,  August  28,  1954,  p.  664. 

25  See  also  pp.  165  ff. 


590       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

deadweight  tonnage  of  18.4  million  were  in  reserve.  In  1952,  the  tonnage 
of  the  United  States  merchant  fleet,  both  active  and  inactive,  was  40  per 
cent  of  the  world  total. 

FOREIGN  TRADE 

Although  the  United  States  is  the  world's  largest  trading  nation,  it  is 
much  less  dependent  on  foreign  trade  for  its  economic  well-being  than 
any  other  major  power  except  the  U.S.S.R.  This  dependence  is  not  only 
small  but  is  also  declining.  Since  World  War  II  the  ratio  of  imports  to 
gross  national  product  has  been  3.3  per  cent  or  less,  as  compared  with 
about  4.5  per  cent  after  World  War  I.  The  corresponding  ratio  in  the  case 
of  exports  is  close  to  4  per  cent.  These  low  ratios  are  in  marked  contrast  to 
those  for  the  United  Kingdom  or  Japan,  for  example,  where  foreign  trade 
is  equal  to  20  and  30  per  cent  respectively  of  the  gross  national  product. 

Important  reasons  for  the  small  and  declining  place  of  foreign  trade  in 
relation  to  total  United  States  production  is  the  richness  of  the  country's 
natural  resources  and  the  efficiency  and  diversity  of  its  industry.  These 
resources  have  enabled  the  United  States  to  feed  its  growing  population 
and  to  provide  the  raw  materials  for  its  rapidly  expanding  industry  with- 
out a  corresponding  increase  in  imports  of  primary  materials.  In  addition, 
United  States  industry  can  produce  virtually  all  of  the  country's  require- 
ments of  manufactures,  and  trade  policies  have  tended  to  restrict  the  entry 
of  competing  foreign  imports.  Various  other  factors  have  operated  to  in- 
crease United  States  self-sufficiency,  such  as  the  development  of  syn- 
thetics like  rayon  for  natural  silk,  synthetic  for  natural  rubber,  more 
efficient  use  of  raw  materials,  and  so  on.  Despite  the  future  prospect  of 
a  rapid  growth  of  United  States  raw  material  imports,  it  is  not  expected 
that  total  imports  will  rise  as  rapidly  as  total  production. 

The  increasing  self-sufficiency  of  the  United  States  economy  partly 
explains  the  postwar  dollar  difficulties  of  the  rest  of  the  world.  As  de- 
scribed in  Chapter  16,  foreign  countries,  particularly  Western  Europe, 
became  increasingly  dependent  on  the  United  States  for  imports,  particu- 
larly of  basic  foodstuffs  and  raw  materials.  However,  exports  to  the  United 
States  and  other  dollar  countries  did  not  rise  correspondingly.  Hence  the 
large  balance-of-payments  deficits  of  the  rest  of  the  world  with  the  United 
States.  During  the  period  1946  to  1953  these  deficits  aggregated  $32.5  bil- 
lion or  more  than  one-fifth  of  the  value  of  United  States  exports  of  goods 
and  services.26  As  a  part  of  its  policy  to  help  the  economic  recovery  of 

26  Commission  on  Foreign  Economic  Policy,  Staff  Papers  (Washington,  1954), 
p.  15, 


THE  UNITED  STATES  AND  CANADA 


591 


the  war-devastated  world,  and  to  build  up  the  strength  of  its  allies  to 
resist  communism,  the  United  States  extended  net  foreign  aid  of  $41  bil- 
lion between  1946  and  1953  to  cover  the  trade  deficit.27  Since  1953,  the 
dollar  problem  has  been  reduced  to  manageable  proportions,  although 
the  dollar  position  of  certain  countries  is  still  precarious.  This  explains  the 
continuing  concern  abroad  about  United  States  foreign  economic  policies, 
particularly  with  respect  to  imports. 

It  should  be  recognized  that  foreign  trade  is  more  important  to  the 
United  States  economy  than  the  low  ratio  of  this  trade  to  total  output 
might  suggest.  As  pointed  out  in  the  section  on  resources,  the  country  is 
heavily  dependent  on  foreign  sources  for  a  number  of  important  and  in 
some  instances  highly  strategic  raw  materials.  Foodstuffs  like  coffee, 
cocoa,  and  sugar,  which  are  considered  important  to  the  United  States 
standard  of  living,  come  wholly  or  in  large  part  from  abroad.  In  the  case 
of  exports,  a  number  of  products,  particularly  agricultural  commodities 
and  machinery,  depend  heavily  on  foreign  markets  (see  Table  18-5 
below). 

TABLE  18-5 
Exports  of  Selected  Commodities  as  Percentage  of  U.  S.  Production  ° 


agricultural  commodities 
(1949-51  average) 


PER  CENT 


NON-AGRICULTURAL  COMMODITIES 

(1951) 


PER  CENT 


Rice 

42.6 

Cotton 

39.0 

Wheat 

33.5 

Tallow 

33.3 

Grain  Sorghum 

29.5 

Soybeans 

25.1 

Tobacco 

25.1 

Lard 

22.0 

Rolling  mill  machinery  and  parts  34.9 

Tractors  22.6 

Sewing  machines  and  parts  22.3 

Textile  machinery  21.6 

Printing  machinery  and  equipment  17.5 

Oilfield  machinery,  tools  and  parts  17.3 

Office  appliances  16.3 

Motor  trucks  and  coaches  15.6 
Agricultural   machinery 

(except  tractors)  11.7 


*  Commission  on  Foreign  Economic  Policy,  Staff  Papers  (Washington,   1954),  p.   5. 

As  is  typical  of  highly-industrialized  countries  the  United  States  imports 
chiefly  crude  and  semi-manufactured  products  and  exports  mostly  manu- 
factures. In  1953,  imports  of  crude  materials,  crude  foodstuffs,  and  semi- 
manufactures were  70  per  cent  of  all  imports.  In  the  case  of  exports, 
finished  manufactures  were  70  per  cent  of  the  total.  Unlike  most  indus- 
trialized countries,  the  United  States  also  is  an  important  exporter  of  bot1! 
foodstuffs  and  crude  materials.  Exports  of  crude  and  manufactured  food- 


27  Ibid.,  p.  40. 


592       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

stuffs  and  of  crude  materials  were  9  per  cent  and  11  per  cent  respectively 
of  total  exports  in  1953. 

In  addition  to  accounting  for  the  largest  share  of  world  trade  the  United 
States  is  the  world's  leading  creditor  nation  and  exporter  of  capital.  At  the 
end  of  1952  United  States  private  and  governmental  investments  abroad 
totaled  $37.5  billion.28  By  contrast,  the  United  States  was  a  debtor  nation 
before  World  War  I.  During  the  period  from  1948  to  1952  net  new  capital 
outflow,  public  and  private,  and  reinvested  earnings  of  United  States- 
owned  subsidiaries,  averaged  over  $2  billion  per  annum. 

The  postwar  years  have  brought  marked  shifts  in  the  geographical  pat- 
tern of  United  States  trade.  In  1953,  55  per  cent  of  this  country's  imports 
came  from  Canada  and  Latin  America  as  compared  with  32  per  cent 
prewar.  Exports  to  Canada  and  Latin  America  increased  to  38  per  cent 
of  the  total  against  32  per  cent  prewar.  Imports  from  Western  Europe 
declined  from  24  per  cent  in  1937  to  20  per  cent  in  1953.  Exports  exclud- 
ing military  aid  to  the  same  areas  fell  from  27  to  17  per  cent.  Trade  with 
the  rest  of  the  world,  chiefly  the  independent  non-sterling  countries  in 
Asia  and  Africa,  also  has  fallen  off  substantially.  The  increased  signifi- 
cance of  imports  from  Canada  and  Latin  America  reflects  the  growing 
role  of  these  areas  as  suppliers  of  crude  materials  and  foodstuffs.  At  the 
same  time  raw  materials  like  tin,  jute,  and  silk,  supplied  by  Asian  coun- 
tries, declined  in  importance.  The  fall  in  European  exports  partly  reflects 
the  reduced  importance  of  United  States  imports  of  manufactures  and 
partly  the  displacement  of  such  imports  by  Canada.  The  expansion  of 
United  States  exports  to  areas  like  Canada  and  Latin  America  has  resulted 
to  an  important  extent  from  the  displacement  of  former  European  sup- 
pliers of  these  areas. 

FUTURE  ECONOMIC  PROSPECTS 

Projecting  future  economic  growth  trends  is  at  best  a  hazardous  under- 
taking. Nonetheless  it  is  a  reasonable  prediction,  barring  unforeseen  dis- 
asters such  as  a  general  war  involving  widespread  physical  destruction, 
that  the  United  States  will  maintain  and  probably  increase  its  absolute 
economic  superiority  for  some  time  in  the  future.  If  this  country's  annual 
rate  of  economic  growth  is  no  greater  over  the  next  two  decades  than  the 
average  rate  of  the  past  century  ( 3  per  cent ) ,  total  output  by  1975  will  be 
more  than  double  that  of  1950,  or  roughly  $570  billion.  This  figure  could 
well  be  on  the  low  side,  however,  in  view  of  present  rapid  technological 

28  Ibid.,  p.  79. 


THE  UNITED  STATES  AND  CANADA  593 

advances  making  for  increased  productivity,  such  as  automation,  and  the 
fact  that  prolonged  depressions  in  the  past  kept  the  rate  lower  than  it 
otherwise  would  have  been.  While  the  United  States  economy  is  still  not 
depression-proof,  it  is  generally  believed  that  with  present  improved  tech- 
niques of  control,  business  fluctuations  will  not  be  severe  in  the  future. 
The  United  States  Joint  Committee  on  the  Economic  Report  has  esti- 
mated the  potential  rate  of  growth  of  this  country's  national  output  at 
4  per  cent  per  year  over  the  next  decade.29  The  maintenance  of  this  rate 
until  1975  would  produce  a  United  States  gross  national  product  of  $728 
billion  in  1950  prices.  As  mentioned  in  Chapter  15  the  rate  of  growth  of 
the  U.S.S.R.  economy  until  the  1970's  is  expected  to  be  higher  than  that 
of  the  United  States,  possibly  4.5  to  5  per  cent  per  annum.  These  rates 
would  give  the  U.S.S.R.  a  gross  national  product  of  $300  billion  to  $350 
billion  by  1975,  as  compared  with  roughly  $100  billion  in  1950.  Thus  while 
the  ratio  of  United  States  output  to  that  of  the  U.S.S.R.,  will  be  less  than 
at  present,  the  absolute  superiority  of  the  United  Sates  will  be  increased 
whether  its  rate  of  growth  is  3  per  cent  or  4  per  cent  per  annum. 

Canada 

No  description  of  the  economic  capabilities  of  the  West  would  be  com- 
plete without  at  least  a  brief  look  at  Canada.  Though  greatly  overshad- 
owed by  the  United  States,  Canada,  with  a  population  of  only  16.5  million 
in  1954,  now  ranks  sixth  among  the  industrial  nations  of  the  world.  She 
is  also  a  leading  exporter  of  industrial  raw  materials  and  foodstuffs.  Dur- 
ing the  past  decade  or  so  Canada  has  been  developing  at  a  spectacular 
rate.  If  present  economic  growth  trends  continue,  Canada  may  well 
emerge  during  the  next  generation  as  the  fourth  or  fifth  industrial  power. 

Canada's  economic  development  has  been  paralleled  by  a  correspond- 
ing growth  in  her  international  status.  Although  a  member  of  the  British 
Commonwealth  of  Nations,  Canada  is  an  independent  and  sovereign 
nation  and  pursues  her  own  vigorous  foreign  policy.  Canadian  troops 
fought  with  United  Nations  forces  in  Korea.  As  a  NATO  country  Canada, 
like  the  United  States,  in  addition  to  providing  armed  forces  has  made 
sizeable  contributions  in  the  form  of  mutual  aid  to  other  member  coun- 
tries. 

Common  economic  and  strategic  interests  as  well  as  close  cultural  ties 
have  made  for  increasing  Canadian-United  States  dependence  and  co- 

29  "Potential  Economic  Growth  of  the  United  States  During  the  Next  Decade," 
83rd  Congress,  2nd  session,  Washington,  1954. 


594       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

operation.  Canada  is  both  the  best  customer  and  chief  supplier  of  the 
United  States.  United  States  capital  has  been  a  major  factor  in  Canada's 
economic  development.  Canada  occupies  a  highly  strategic  position  from 
the  point  of  view  of  the  security  of  the  United  States  in  today's  era  of 
long-range  bombers  and  atomic  missiles,  since  most  of  the  great  circle 
routes  from  the  United  States  and  Europe  pass  over  Canada.  Millions  of 
Canadians  have  crossed  the  border  to  become  American  citizens. 


GEOGRAPHY  AND  PEOPLE 

Canada  is  the  second  largest  country  in  the  world  with  a  total  area  of 
3.8  million  square  miles.  It  embraces  all  of  the  northern  half  of  the  North 
American  continent  except  Alaska,  Greenland,  and  the  French  islands  of 
St.  Pierre  and  St.  Miquelon.  However,  cold  climatic  conditions  limit  the 
habitable  area  of  Canada  to  less  than  10  per  cent  of  the  total  as  compared 
with  more  than  50  per  cent  for  the  United  States.  With  the  incorporation 
of  Newfoundland  in  1949,  Canada  now  comprises  ten  provinces  and  the 
Yukon  and  Northwest  Territories. 

The  geography  of  Canada  is  similar  to  that  of  the  United  States  in  many 
important  respects.  Western  Canada,  like  Western  United  States,  is  char- 
acterized by  rugged  mountains  and  plateaus.  The  interior  plains  of  the  Ca- 
nadian prairie  provinces  are  an  extension  of  the  Great  Plains  and  lowlands 
of  the  United  States.  In  the  east  Canada  has  its  mountainous  and  hilly  Ap- 
palachian region  which  includes  all  of  the  eastern  provinces.  The  largest 
physiographic  division  of  Canada  is  the  Laurentian  shield,  a  vast  V- 
shaped  area  of  1.8  million  square  miles  which  extends  from  the  interior 
plains  to  the  coast  of  Labrador.  This  region  is  marked  by  rugged  slopes 
of  rocky  hills  broken  by  river  valleys  and  is  the  source  of  most  of  Canada's 
mineral  wealth.  Between  the  Appalachians  and  the  Shield  are  the  St. 
Lawrence  lowlands— a  plain  of  low  relief  extending  from  Quebec  City  to 
Lake  Huron,  a  distance  of  600  miles.30 

Most  major  Canadian  rivers,  except  the  St.  Lawrence,  are  of  limited 
utility  for  transportation  since  they  flow  away  from  the  more  settled  re- 
gions to  the  cold  northern  waters.  Thus  the  Nelson-Saskatchewan  flows 
into  the  Hudson  Bay  and  the  Mackenzie-Athabaska  flows  into  the  Arctic. 
However,  the  St.  Lawrence  and  the  Great  Lakes  afford  an  unequalled 
inland  navigation  system,  extending  for  a  distance  of  2,000  miles  through 
the  most  highly  developed  regions  of  Canada. 

According  to  the  1951  Census,  Canada  had  a  population  of  just  over 

30  Stamp  and  Suggate,  op.  cit.,  pp.  155-158. 


THE  UNITED  STATES  AND  CANADA  595 

14  million.  The  population  is  increasing  at  the  rapid  rate  of  more  than 
2  per  cent  per  annum,  chiefly  as  a  result  of  natural  increase,  but  partly 
through  immigration  and  amounted  to  16.5  million  in  1954.  Immigration 
has  increased  significantly  since  the  war,  mostly  because  of  highly  prosper- 
ous economic  conditions.  United  Nations  population  experts  have  esti- 
mated that  Canada's  population  should  reach  20  million  by  1980. 

The  two  basic  stocks  of  Canada's  population  are  French  and  English 
(cf.  Fig.  11-2,  p.  391).  The  French  are  primarily  the  descendants  of  the 
original  seventeenth  and  eighteenth  century  colonists.  Of  the  1951  popu- 
lation of  14  million,  4.3  million  were  of  French  extraction  and  6.7  million 
British.  Other  Europeans  number  2.5  million.  The  remaining  population 
consists  mostly  of  Indians  and  a  few  Eskimos.  The  large  French  minority 
has  been  a  source  of  considerable  social  and  policital  friction  throughout 
Canada's  history.  Most  Frenchmen  still  speak  their  mother  tongue  and 
observe  the  customs  and  laws  of  their  ancestors.  "Not  even  189  years  of 
British  rule  have  changed  them.  The  difference  between  a  French  and  a 
British  Canadian  is  greater  by  far  than  between  a  British  Canadian  and  an 
American."  31 

Population  density  (cf.  Fig.  2-9,  p.  48)  is  low,  averaging  3.92  persons 
per  square  mile  in  1951.  The  cold  and  inhospitable  Northwest  and  Yukon 
territories  which  account  for  almost  40  per  cent  of  the  area  of  Canada  had 
a  population  density  of  only  about  2  persons  per  100  square  miles  while 
the  average  density  in  the  provinces  was  only  6.6  persons  per  square  mile. 
Climatic  factors  keep  most  of  Canada's  population  in  the  south.  Half  of 
Canada's  population  lives  in  a  narrow  band,  100  to  125  miles  from  the 
Canadian-United  States  border,  and  90  per  cent  live  200  to  225  miles  from 
the  border.  Two-thirds  of  the  population  live  in  the  provinces  of  Ontario 
and  Quebec. 

Until  fairly  recently  the  movement  of  population  from  east  to  west  in 
Canada  closely  paralleled  that  of  the  United  States.  Thus  between  1871 
and  1951  the  proportion  of  Canada's  total  population  living  in  the  western 
provinces  of  Manitoba,  Alberta,  Saskatchewan,  and  British  Columbia  in- 
creased from  less  than  2  per  cent  to  26  per  cent.  This  movement  was 
greatly  stimulated  by  the  completion  of  the  transcontinental  railway  in 
1885  which  opened  up  the  rich  agricultural  lands  of  the  west.  While  the 
population  of  British  Columbia  has  continued  to  increase  relative  to  the 
rest  of  the  country  during  the  past  decade,  that  of  the  prairie  provinces 
has  been  declining,  reflecting  the  falling  relative  importance  of  agricul- 

31  K.  Munro,  "Now  Canada  Comes  of  Age,"  New  York  Times  Magazine,  March 
30,  1952;  see  also  p.  390. 


596       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

ture.  In  recent  years  there  has  been  a  tendency  for  the  population  to  move 
in  a  more  northerly  direction.  The  chief  stimulus  for  this  movement  has 
not  been  opportunities  in  agriculture,  like  the  movement  to  the  west,  but 
rather  the  growth  of  mining  activity.  The  quest  for  and  exploitation  of 
mineral  deposits  has  created  dozens  of  new  towns  virtually  in  the  wilder- 
ness. One  example  is  the  town  of  Kitimat,  a  hundred  miles  south  of  the 
Alaskan  border,  which  is  the  site  of  the  largest  aluminum  expansion  proj- 
ect in  the  Free  World.  Four  years  ago  Kitimat  was  an  Indian  fishing  vil- 
lage. Today  it  has  a  population  of  5,000  and  by  1959,  when  the  project  is 
completed,  it  is  expected  to  have  20,000. 32  Another  settlement  has  mush- 
roomed at  the  Burnt  Creek  iron  ore  mine  project  on  the  Quebec-Labrador 
boundary,  360  miles  north  of  Seven  Islands  on  the  Gulf  of  St.  Lawrence. 
Or  again,  the  discovery  of  vast  uranium  deposits  at  Blind  River  in  the  On- 
tario wilderness  is  changing  and  has  changed  a  slumbering  lumber  town  of 
3,000  people  into  a  thriving  community  of  15,000  persons  in  a  few  years. 
While  the  movement  northward  has  been  hampered  by  the  lack  of  rail 
and  highway  transport,  it  has  proceeded  much  more  rapidly  than  other- 
wise would  have  been  possible  as  a  result  of  the  availability  of  air  trans- 
port. Thus  mining  operations  began  at  Burnt  Creek  with  equipment  flown 
in  by  air  one  year  before  the  railroad  from  Seven  Islands  was  completed. 

RESOURCES 

Canada's  rapid  economic  growth  of  recent  years  has  been  based  to  a 
very  important  degree  on  the  exploitation  of  the  country's  rich  natural 
resources  (cf.  Fig.  18-2).  Canada  is  still  in  the  stage  of  economic  develop- 
ment where  the  exploitation  of  its  natural  resources  can  significantly  affect 
the  entire  economy.  Thus  the  iron  ore  deposits  of  Ungava  and  northern 
Quebec  "are  directly  responsible  for  the  railways  now  being  constructed 
from  the  St.  Lawrence  and  the  'opening  up'  of  new  lands.  The  past  three 
years  have  seen  a  significant  change  in  the  whole  of  Canada's  economy 
through  the  Alberta  oil  strikes."  33  Since  Canada's  natural  resources  are 
still  relatively  undeveloped,  their  exploitation  is  likely  to  have  an  impor- 
tant influence  on  the  pattern  of  economic  growth  for  some  years  to  come. 
Canada's  frontier  is  still  an  expanding  one  and  probably  her  greatest  need 
is  more  people.  Some  authorities  have  estimated  Canada  could  support  a 
population  of  100  million.34 

Agriculture.  Though  less  well-endowed  than  the  United  States  with 

32  L.  D.  Stamp,  Our  Undeveloped  World  (London,  1953),  p.  122. 

33  Ibid.,  p.  122. 

34  Stamp  and  Suggate,  op.  cit.,  p.  184. 


THE  UNITED  STATES  AND  CANADA  597 

land  suitable  for  agriculture,  despite  its  greater  area,  Canada's  agricul- 
tural land  base  is  nonetheless  more  than  adequate  in  relation  to  its  popu- 
lation. United  Nations  estimates  place  Canada's  arable  land  area  at  93 
million  acres  ( 1950 ) ,  or  more  than  6  acres  per  capita.  Unoccupied  but 
potentially  productive  agricultural  land  exceeds  170  million  acres.  Like 
the  United  States,  Canada  should  experience  no  difficulty  for  the  foresee- 
able future  in  feeding  its  growing  population  and  at  the  same  time  pro- 
viding a  sizeable  volume  of  exports. 

Forest.  Canada's  forest  resources  are  among  the  richest  in  the  world. 
They  are  the  basis  of  Canada's  vast  timber  and  pulp  and  paper  industry 
which  for  some  time  has  exceeded  all  other  industries  in  importance. 
Canada  produces  more  than  one-half  the  world's  newsprint  and  is  a  major 
producer  and  exporter  of  wood  pulp  and  timber.  The  country's  total  lum- 
ber stand  on  accessible  and  inaccessible  land  is  about  two-thirds  that  of 
the  United  States.  However,  roughly  45  per  cent  of  this  stand  is  at  present 
inaccessible,  against  10  per  cent  for  the  United  States.35  The  trees  are 
predominantly  softwood,  and  these  enjoy  the  widest  general  demand. 

Minerals.  Canada  possesses  an  abundance  of  mineral  and  fuel  re- 
sources. Although  production  is  still  small,  Canada's  reserves  of  high- 
grade  iron  ore  are  among  the  largest  in  the  world.  Copper,  nickel,  lead, 
zinc,  uranium,  and  asbestos  reserves  are  more  than  adequate  to  cover 
future  needs  for  some  years  to  come  and  are  exploited  primarily  for 
export.  Like  the  United  States,  Canada's  principal  mineral  deficiencies 
are  in  the  ferro-alloys— chromium,  manganese,  tin,  tungsten,  and  molyb- 
denum. 

Canada  has  large  reserves  of  high-grade  bituminous  coal  suitable  for 
coking.  However,  these  reserves  are  located  mainly  in  the  maritime  and 
prairie  provinces  and  in  British  Columbia,  and  not  in  the  industrialized 
provinces  of  Ontario  and  Quebec.  Transportation  savings  make  it  more 
economical  for  these  two  provinces  to  buy  coal  from  nearby  United  States 
sources,  which  explains  why  Canada  is  a  large  net  importer  of  coal. 

Since  1947,  large  reserves  of  oil  and  natural  gas  have  been  discovered 
in  western  Canada.  Proved  reserves  now  amount  to  less  than  one  per  cent 
of  the  Free  World  total.  However,  expert  geologists  estimate  potential 
reserves  may  amount  to  as  much  as  50  billion  barrels  or  more  than  10  per 
cent  of  the  present  reserves  of  the  Free  World.36  While  Canada  now 
imports  about  half  of  its  petroleum  requirements,  it  should  achieve  sta- 

35  The  President's  Materials  Policy  Commission,  op.  cit.,  Vol.  5,  p.  53. 

36  H.  M.  H.  A.  Van  Der  Valk,  The  Economic  Future  of  Canada  (New  York,  1954), 
p.  54. 


598       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

tistical  self-sufficiency  in  a  few  years.  Locational  factors,  however,  will 
make  it  economical  for  Canada  to  continue  to  import  some  petroleum.  At 
present  many  gas  wells  have  been  closed  in  Canada  for  lack  of  markets, 
but  in  time  the  construction  of  pipelines  to  major  consuming  areas  will 
help  to  overcome  this  problem. 

Large  areas  of  Canada  enjoy  an  abundance  of  cheap  hydro-electric 
power.  Canada  ranks  after  the  United  States  in  installed  hydro-electric 
capacity.  Low-cost  hydro-electric  power  has  been  an  important  factor  in 
Canada's  industrial  development.  It  has  compensated  to  an  important 
extent  for  the  lack  of  coal  in  industrialized  Ontario  and  Quebec.  It  has 
been  the  basis  for  the  development  of  Canada's  huge  aluminum  as  well 
as  other  electro-metallurgical  industries,  and  has  been  extremely  impor- 
tant to  the  growth  of  the  pulp  and  paper  industry  which  is  a  large  user 
of  electric  power.  So  far  only  about  one-quarter  of  Canada's  hydro- 
electric resources  have  been  developed.  Large  untapped  sources  are  still 
available  for  exploitation  in  British  Columbia,  Manitoba,  Northern  On- 
tario, Quebec,  and  Labrador. 

GENERAL  ECONOMIC  CHARACTERISTICS 

As  mentioned  previously  production  in  Canada  has  been  growing  at  a 
rapid  rate,  almost  doubling  between  1939  and  1951.  Average  per  capita 
gross  national  product  in  1953  was  roughly  $1,600  or  more  than  twice  the 
average  of  Free  Europe.  Though  less  industrialized  than  the  United 
States,  Canada's  industry  greatly  exceeds  agriculture  in  importance.  In 
1952  manufactures  accounted  for  29  per  cent  of  the  net  domestic  product 
as  against  14.2  per  cent  for  agriculture. 

As  in  any  rapidly  developing  country  agriculture  has  been  declining  in 
relative  importance  for  some  time.  At  the  beginning  of  the  century  40  per 
cent  of  Canada's  labor  force  was  engaged  in  agriculture  and  by  1951  the 
percentage  had  declined  to  19  per  cent.  The  relative  contribution  of  agri- 
culture to  total  output  has  also  been  falling  but  to  a  lesser  extent.  The 
prairie  provinces,  like  the  great  plains  of  the  United  States,  are  Canada's 
principal  agricultural  region.  Their  main  crop  is  wheat,  although  the  trend 
is  toward  greater  diversification.  Canada  produces  enough  wheat  to  feed 
100  million  people.  The  chief  crops  in  the  maritime  provinces  are  potatoes 
and  apples,  while  in  Ontario  and  Quebec  mixed  farming  predominates. 
Like  the  United  States,  Canada  has  had  an  agricultural  surplus  problem 
for  some  years. 

Employment  in  industry  outnumbers  employment  in  agriculture  two 


THE  UNITED  STATES  AND  CANADA  599 

to  one.  The  principal  industries  are  pulp  and  paper,  food  processing,  and 
non-ferrous  smelting  and  refining  respectively.  Production  of  more  com- 
plex industrial  products  such  as  machinery  and  equipment  tends  to  be 
limited  by  the  small  size  of  the  Canadian  market.  Ontario  and  Quebec 
account  for  roughly  80  per  cent  of  all  manufactures.  The  industrial  pre- 
dominance of  these  two  eastern  provinces  owes  much  to  the  availability 
of  cheap  hydro-electric  power,  their  proximity  to  the  high-quality  coal 
of  the  eastern  Appalachian  region  of  the  United  States,  and  the  superb 
inland  water  transport  system  of  the  St.  Lawrence  River  and  the  Great 
Lakes.  American  investors  have  a  large  stake  in  Canadian  industry.  It  has 
been  estimated  that  United  States-controlled  industrial  enterprises  rep- 
resent about  one-third  of  the  total  investment  in  Canadian  industry.37 
Total  United  States  investments  in  Canada  amounted  to  $8  billion  in  1952. 
Canada's  prosperity  is  heavily  dependent  on  foreign  trade.  Approxi- 
mately one-quarter  to  one-fifth  of  the  country's  gross  national  product 
derives  from  exports.  Moreover  exports  are  primarily  processed  raw  ma- 
terials like  foodstuffs,  wood  products,  pulp  and  paper,  and  metals,  and 
are  somewhat  lacking  in  diversification.  As  a  result  Canada  is  relatively 
vulnerable  to  external  economic  developments  though  by  no  means  to  the 
same  degree  as  the  typical  underdeveloped  country.  Finished  manufac- 
tures, chiefly  machinery  and  equipment,  are  Canada's  principal  imports. 
Since  World  War  II  the  United  States  has  replaced  the  United  Kingdom 
as  Canada's  principal  trading  partner.  In  1953,  some  59  per  cent  of 
Canada's  exports  went  to  the  United  States  and  74  per  cent  of  its  imports 
came  from  the  same  source. 

OUTLOOK 

Canada's  future  economic  prospects  are  considered  to  be  highly  favor- 
able. Its  population  and  economic  growth  rates  are  among  the  most  rapid 
in  the  Free  World,  and  it  has  an  abundance  of  natural  resources.  One 
authority  in  a  recent  study  estimated  that  Canada  might  have  a  gross 
national  product  of  $80  billion  in  1952  prices  by  1980. 3S  This  estimate  may 
well  be  on  the  high  side.  Nonetheless  there  is  good  reason  to  believe 
Canada  will  continue  to  develop  more  rapidly  than  most  other  industrial- 
ized nations  and  that  it  will  emerge  before  the  end  of  the  century  as  one 
of  the  world's  leading  economic  powers.  In  this  process  it  has  been 
prophesied  by  the  Governor  of  the  Bank  of  Canada  that  "Canada  would 

37  Ibid.,  p.  124. 

38  Ibid. 


600        THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

be  very  much  less  dependent  on  its  export  trades,  much  more  highly  de- 
veloped in  its  secondary  and  tertiary  industries,  that  it  would  have  repatri- 
ated much  of  the  ownership  of  basic  industries  now  held  in  the  United 
States,  and  that  the  process  of  the  next  twenty  years  would  be  increasing 
'Canadianization'  rather  than  'Continentalization.'"  39 

39  The  Economist,  May  28,  1955,  p.  746. 


CHAPTER 


19 


The  Challenge  or  the 
Underdeveloped  Areas 


GENERAL  ECONOMIC  CHARACTERISTICS 

The  term  underdeveloped  has  a  number  of  connotations.  Here  the  term 
is  used  to  describe  countries  that  are  unable  to  provide  what  they  consider 
to  be  acceptable  levels  of  living  for  the  mass  of  their  populations.  If  we 
arbitrarily  take  a  figure  of  $300  per  capita  as  a  minimum  acceptable  annual 
income,  we  find  that  countries  which  fall  into  the  underdeveloped  category 
account  for  most  of  the  free  world's  population  and  land  area.  In  1953, 
with  a  population  in  excess  of  one  billion,  the  underdeveloped  countries 
had  70  per  cent  of  the  peoples  of  the  non-Communist  world.  Their  land 
area  is  also  roughly  70  per  cent  of  the  total.  They  are  to  be  found  in  all 
hemispheres  and  on  every  continent,  but  primarily  in  Asia,  Africa,  and 
Latin  America  ( cf.  Fig.  14-3,  p.  468 ) . 

As  might  be  expected,  given  the  wide  differences  in  their  natural  and 
cultural  environments,  the  underdeveloped  areas  have  extremely  diverse 
economies.  Despite  these  diversities,  the  underdeveloped  areas  share 
enough  common  characteristics  to  permit  meaningful  generalization  about 
their  economies,  which  are  more  directly  affected  by  geographical  factors 
than  are  those  of  the  more  highly  developed  areas,  especially  the  indus- 
trialized and  urbanized  countries.  To  understand  the  basic  features  of 
their  economic  systems,  especially  those  rooted  in  the  relationships  of 
man  to  his  natural  environment,  is  a  prerequisite  for  the  understanding 
of  the  economic  and  political  geography  of  the  underdeveloped  countries. 

601 


602       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

The  greater  the  degree  of  their  underdevelopment,  the  greater  is  the  in- 
terrelationship of  economic  and  political  factors  in  their  human  geog- 
raphy. 

The  outstanding  characteristic  that  the  underdeveloped  countries  have 
in  common  is  of  course  their  poverty.  Most  of  the  population  live  at,  or 
close  to,  bare  subsistence  levels.  Average  per  capita  incomes  amounted  to 
roughly  $70  in  1949  compared  with  $690  for  the  more  developed  regions 
and  $1,450  for  the  United  States.1  Inequality  in  the  distribution  of  income 
between  underdeveloped  and  developed  countries  is  no  less  marked  than 
that  between  individuals  within  a  single  country.  Of  an  estimated  national 
income  among  Free  World  countries  of  $460  billion  in  1949,  the  devel- 
oped countries  accounted  for  $350  billion  or  roughly  75  per  cent.  In  other 
words,  the  developed  countries  with  30  per  cent  of  the  population  of  the 
non-Communist  world  accounted  for  more  than  three-quarters  of  the 
total  output  of  goods  and  services. 

Despite  the  efforts  of  the  underdeveloped  countries  to  accelerate  their 
economic  growth,  the  gap  between  incomes  in  the  underdeveloped  and 
the  developed  countries  continues  to  increase.  According  to  Professor 
Simon  Kuznets,  this  process  has  been  going  on  for  more  than  a  century.2 
The  indications  are  this  gap  will  continue  to  widen  for  the  indefinite 
future.  The  reasons  are  partly  the  low  economic  growth  rates  in  many 
underdeveloped  areas  but  primarily  the  fact  that  these  rates  apply  to  a 
much  lower  absolute  base  than  in  the  case  of  the  industrialized  areas. 

Low  living  standards  are  evidenced  by  inadequate  diets,  primitive 
housing,  poor  health,  and  low  levels  of  education.  Most  of  the  inhabitants 
of  the  underdeveloped  areas  have  a  daily  per  capita  food  supply  of  less 
than  2,200  calories  per  day,  or  20  per  cent  below  what  is  considered  the 
minimum  for  health  and  efficiency.  This  compares  with  3,000  calories  or 
more  for  the  industrialized  countries.  These  calorie  differences  do  not  take 
into  account  qualitative  differences:  for  example,  consumption  of  animal 
proteins  in  the  underdeveloped  areas  is  one-fourth  of  that  in  developed 
countries.  Endemic  and  other  diseases  are  common  and  undermine  seri- 
ously the  vitality  of  the  people.  In  many  of  these  countries,  the  geography 
of  diseases  is  an  integral  part  of  their  economic  and  political  geography: 
wherever  there  is  the  tsetse  fly,  sleeping  sickness  may  bar  social  and  politi- 
cal development.  Almost  every  African  native  is  infested  with  some  type 

1  United  Nations,  Per  Capita  Incomes  of  Seventy  Countries— 1949  (New  York, 
October,  1950). 

2  "Underdeveloped  Countries  and  the  Pre-Industrial  Phase  In  the  Advanced  Coun- 
tries: An  Attempt  at  Comparison,"  delivered  before  the  United  Nations  Population 
Conference  in  Rome,  September,  1954. 


THE  CHALLENGE  OF  THE  UNDERDEVELOPED  AREAS       603 

of  intestinal  worm,  and  over  large  areas  a  great  proportion  of  the  people 
suffer  from  malaria,  plague,  yaws,  and  syphilis."  However  considerable 
progress  has  been  made  in  coping  with  these  diseases  during  the  past  15 
years  in  East  and  Central  Africa.  Birth  and  mortality  rates  are  high  and 
life  expectancy  is  low.  In  the  underdeveloped  areas  as  a  whole,  ex- 
pectation of  life  at  birth  is  less  than  35  years  as  against  60  years  in  the 
developed  regions.  Approximately  two-thirds  of  the  male  population  are 
illiterate,  compared  with  5  per  cent  in  developed  countries.  The  worker 
force  is  lacking  in  specialized  training  and  skills.  Although  it  is  impossible 
to  measure  in  reasonably  accurate  statistical  terms  the  degree  of  literacy 
and  technical  skills  in  underdeveloped  areas,  it  must  be  realized  that  these 
factors  are  of  considerable  significance  in  evaluating  the  usefulness,  actual 
and  potential,  of  the  resources  of  an  area  to  man  and  his  political  organi- 
zations.4 The  differentiation  in  literacy  and  skills  itself  defies  analysis,  at 
least  in  many  of  the  areas  with  which  we  are  concerned  (cf.  Fig.  13-1,  2, 
pp.  442,  444).  These  difficulties,  however,  only  underline  the  need  for 
exploration  of  the  intangible  factors  by  trying  to  equate  the  human  and 
the  natural  resources  of  such  an  area  within  political  boundaries. 

Agriculture  is  the  principal  economic  activity.  More  than  60  per  cent 
of  the  people  in  the  underdeveloped  areas  depend  on  agriculture  for  a 
livelihood  compared  with  30  per  cent  or  less  in  industrialized  countries 
( see  Table  19-1 ) .  Thus  with  respect  to  the  distribution  of  the  labor  force, 
the  underdeveloped  countries  stand  where  the  developed  countries  stood 
a  hundred  to  a  hundred  and  fifty  years  ago.  Many  rural  areas  are  on  the 
bare  fringe  of  the  money  economy.  Farmers  produce  primarily  for  their 
own  use  and  exchanges  frequently  involve  barter. 

Land  is  scarce  relative  to  population  in  many  underdeveloped  areas.  As 
a  consequence,  average  farm  holdings  are  generally  very  small,  usually 
less  than  what  is  considered  the  minimum  for  efficient  operation.  Man}' 
areas  have  semi-feudal  agricultural  systems  characterized  by  large  es- 
tates. Large  estates  are  widespread  in  the  Caribbean,  throughout  South 
America,  in  South  East  Asia,  in  Ceylon,  and  in  parts  of  East  Africa.5 
Tenancy  commonly  associated  with  large  estates  is  often  characterized  by 
high  rents  and  insecurity  of  tenure.  In  certain  areas,  notably  Africa  south 
of  the  Sahara,  communal  tenure  is  the  most  common  form  of  land  owner- 
ship. 

The  underdeveloped  countries  account  for  less  than  10  per  cent  of  the 

3  "Annual  Medical  Report  for  Kenya  (1928),"  as  quoted  in  W.  Macmillan,  Africa 
Emergent  (London,  1938),  pp.  30-37. 

4  See  pp.  499-501. 

5  United  Nations,  Land  Reform  (New  York,  1951),  p.  18. 


604        THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

Free  World's  industrial  output.  Industry  is  confined  largely  to  the  proces- 
sing of  raw  materials  for  export  and  the  manufacture  of  consumers  goods 
for  domestic  consumption.  In  many  areas  industry  is  controlled  by  foreign 
investors  and  its  impact  on  the  total  economy  is  peripheral.  Handicrafts 
still  account  for  a  considerable  share  of  the  manufacturing  output  in  many 
areas.  Only  a  few  countries  have  any  heavy  industry,  and  crude  steel  pro- 
duction is  less  than  3  per  cent  of  the  Free  World  total. 

TABLE   19-1 
Proportion  of  World  Population  in  Agriculture,  1949  * 


AREA 

TOTAL 
POPULATION 
(  MILLIONS  ) 

AGRICULTURAL 
POPULATION 
(  MILLIONS  ) 

AGRICULTURAL 

POPULATION  AS 

PERCENTAGE 

OF  TOTAL 

North  America  a 

163 

33 

20 

Europe 

391 

129 

33 

Oceania 

12 

4 

33 

South  America 

107 

64 

60 

Central  America  b 

50 

33 

67 

Asia 

1,255 

878 

70 

Africa 

198 

146 

74 

WORLD  TOTAL 

2,176 

1,287 

59 

a  United  States  and  Canada. 

b  Includes  Mexico. 

*  United  Nations,   Food  and  Agriculture  Organization,    Yearbook   of  Food  and  Agriculture,   1950,  p.   16. 


Productivity  per  worker  in  agriculture  and  industry  is  low.  Yields  per 
person  in  agriculture  in  1947-48  were  well  below  the  world  average  and 
far  less  than  in  the  United  States  or  in  Western  Europe  ( see  Table  19-2 ) . 

TABLE   19-2 
Productivity  of  Agricultural  Population  by  Continents,   1947-48  * 


CONTINENT 


yields  per  person 
in  agriculture 
(metric  tons) 


World  Average 

North  and  Central  America 

South  America 

Europe 

Oceania 

Asia 

Africa 


0.42 

2.57 
0.48 
0.88 
2.38 
0.22 
0.77 


*  Food  and  Agriculture  Organization  of  the  United  Nations,  Monthly  Bulletin  of  Food  and  Agricultural 
Statistics,  Vol.  2,  No.  9  (September,   1949). 


THE  CHALLENGE  OF  THE  UNDERDEVELOPED  AREAS       605 

Various  factors  account  for  this  low  productivity,  including  underem- 
ployment of  labor,  lack  of  equipment,  backward  technology,  limited  use 
of  fertilizers,  use  of  inferior  land,  and  unfavorable  climate.  The  limited 
use  of  mechanical  energy  is  indicated  by  the  fact  that  consumption  of 
commercial  sources  of  energy  in  underdeveloped  areas  is  one-sixteenth 
or  less  that  in  the  United  States.  Underemployment  of  labor  is  particularly 
significant  in  the  densely  populated  countries  of  Asia  where  lack  of  alter- 
native opportunities  leads  to  overcrowding  of  farms.  The  following  data 
on  income  of  workers  in  manufacturing  and  handicrafts  for  selected  coun- 
tries in  1948  indicates  that  productivity  per  industrial  worker  in  under- 
developed countries,  compared  with  developed  countries,  is  even  less 
favorable  than  in  agriculture.6 


World 

$  910 

United  States 

4110 

Canada 

3000 

United  Kingdom 

1450 

Middle  America 

720 

South  America 

520 

Turkey 

400 

Africa 

265 

India 

200 

Communications  and  transportation  facilities  are  poorly  developed.  For 
example,  in  1951,  the  highly  developed  countries,  the  United  States  and 
Canada  had  over  300  telephone  instruments  in  use  per  1000  population  as 
against  2  instruments  per  1000  in  the  underdeveloped  countries.  Most 
underdeveloped  areas  are  inadequately  serviced  by  any  form  of  transpor- 
tation. Whereas  the  United  States  and  Canada  moved  about  6,000  ton 
miles  of  freight  per  capita  per  annum  in  1951,  the  underdeveloped  coun- 
tries generally  carried  less  than  130  tons  per  capita.  The  number  of  motor 
vehicles  in  use  in  the  underdeveloped  areas  in  relation  to  population  was 
less  than  3  per  cent  of  that  in  the  developed  countries.7 

Two  or  three  primary  products  generally  account  for  the  bulk  of  all 
exports.  Export  earnings  are  extremely  volatile  because  of  wide  cyclical 
swings  in  the  world  market  demand  for  such  products.  Thus  the  econo- 
mies of  the  underdeveloped  countries  are  highly  vulnerable  to  external 
market  forces  over  which  they  have  relatively  little  control.  A  United 
Nations'  study  showed  average  annual  fluctuations  of  35  per  cent  in  pro- 

6  W.  S.  and  E.  S.  Woytinsky,  World  Population  and  Production  Trends  and  Outlook 
(New  York,  1953),  p.  1013. 

7  United  Nations,  Statistical  Yearbook,  1954. 


606       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

ceeds  from  exports  of  a  number  of  important  primary  products  during  the 
first  half  of  the  twentieth  century.8 

With  the  notable  exception  of  Latin  America,  the  rate  of  economic 
growth  in  many  underdeveloped  areas  in  recent  decades  has  barely  kept 
pace  with  the  increase  in  population.  As  a  result,  per  capita  real  incomes 
have  remained  almost  stationary  at  a  time  when  they  have  been  rising 
rapidly  in  the  industrialized  countries  of  the  West. 

Many  serious  obstacles  stand  in  the  way  of  the  efforts  of  the  under- 
developed countries  to  speed  up  their  rate  of  economic  development.  Low 
incomes  leave  only  a  relatively  small  margin  for  savings  and  investment. 
The  rate  of  capital  formation  in  most  underdeveloped  areas  is  just  about 
adequate  to  keep  up  with  the  population  growth,  hence  any  significant 
increase  in  the  rate  of  domestic  capital  formation  would  require  a  reduc- 
tion of  existing  low  living  standards.  Not  many  governments  of  under- 
developed areas  have  the  requisite  administrative  skills  to  divert  more 
production  from  consumption  into  investment,  and  might  well  be  unwill- 
ing to  assume  the  attendant  political  risks. 

Lack  of  domestic  savings  can  of  course  be  compensated  by  infusions  of 
capital  from  abroad.  The  amount  required  to  induce  a  satisfactory  rate  of 
economic  growth  in  the  underdeveloped  areas  would  be  extremely  large. 
A  group  of  experts  appointed  by  the  Secretary-General  of  the  United 
Nations  estimated  that  capital  imports  of  more  than  $10  billion  per  year 
would  be  required  to  raise  per  capita  incomes  in  the  underdeveloped 
areas  by  2  per  cent  per  annum.9  This  compares  with  the  current  flow  of 
not  much  more  than  $1  billion  per  annum. 

Lack  of  capital  is  by  no  means  the  only  obstacle  to  economic  progress. 
In  many  areas  economic  development  will  require  fundamental  changes 
in  the  social  and  economic  structure  of  society  and  massive  efforts  to  raise 
levels  of  education.  Many  parts  of  Africa,  for  example,  are  only  just 
emerging  from  tribal  forms  of  society  where  land  is  held  in  common  and 
the  experimental  or  scientific  attitude  is  virtually  unknown.  Other  soci- 
eties in  parts  of  the  Middle  East  and  Latin  America  are  still  semi-feudal 
in  their  essential  characteristics.  Wealth  and  power  are  associated  with 
the  ownership  of  land  rather  than  success  in  industry  and  trade.  Absentee 
ownership  and  farm  tenancy  are  widespread,  thereby  reducing  incentives 
to  improve  existing  inefficient  farming  methods.  Much  wealth  is  wasted  in 
conspicuous  consumption.  Moreover,  many  members  of  the  ruling  classes 

s  Relation  of  Fluctuations  in  the  Prices  of  Primary  Commodities  to  the  Ability  of 
the  Under-Developed  Countries  to  Obtain  Foreign  Exchange  (July  5,  1951). 

9  United  Nations,  Measures  for  the  Economic  Development  of  Under-Developed 
Countries  (New  York,  May,  1951). 


THE  CHALLENGE  OF  THE  UNDERDEVELOPED  AREAS       607 

are  resistant  to  economic  progress  because  of  the  threat  that  it  poses  to 
their  power  and  prestige. 

Governments  are  frequently  inefficient  and  corrupt,  and  political  in- 
stability and  civil  disorder  may  be  endemic.  As  a  result,  the  atmosphere  of 
confidence  about  the  future  which  is  essential  to  sustained  economic  prog- 
ress is  often  lacking. 

Many  underdeveloped  areas  lack  an  entrepreneurial  class  capable  and 
willing  to  exploit  the  advances  of  modern  technology.  Investors  tend  to 
favor  commercial  ventures  offering  high  and  quick  returns.  Consequently, 
the  development  of  many  of  the  basic  services  required  for  economic 
growth,  such  as  power,  transport,  and  communications,  is  generally  in- 
adequate. 

Demographic  factors  (cf.  Fig.  9-2,  p.  296)  pose  serious  obstacles  to 
economic  development.  Most  of  today's  highly  developed  countries  had 
low  rates  of  population  increase  during  their  pre-industrial  periods.  Rapid 
population  growth  came  after  they  began  to  develop.  By  contrast,  a  num- 
ber of  underdeveloped  countries— the  Philippines,  Thailand,  Malaya,  Cey- 
lon, Bolivia— have  rates  of  population  increase  double  those  of  the  de- 
veloped countries  at  a  comparable  stage  of  development.  This  imposes  a 
heavy  investment  burden  on  the  limited  savings  of  these  countries  to  sup- 
port the  increments  to  their  populations.  Certain  areas,  notably  South 
Asia,  face  both  overpopulation  and  the  prospect  of  a  rapid  rise  in  the  rate 
of  population  growth.  India's  population,  for  example,  probably  exceeds 
the  optimum  relative  to  its  resources.  Increments  to  the  labor  force,  there- 
fore, mean  lower  returns  per  worker  because  of  the  necessity  of  having  to 
exploit  progressively  inferior  resources.  Inferior  resources  can  be  offset  by 
improved  technology,  but  this  requires  increased  amounts  of  capital  per 
worker  and  thereby  raises  the  cost  of  economic  development. 

Better  public  health  measures  are  expected  to  bring  about  a  substantial 
lowering  of  death  rates  in  the  years  immediately  ahead  without  a  corre- 
sponding decline  in  birth  rates.  As  a  result,  India's  annual  rate  of  popula- 
tion increase  for  example  might  rise  to  about  2  per  cent  in  the  next  decade 
or  so  as  compared  with  about  1.25  per  cent  each  year  since  the  war.  This 
will  mean  a  yearly  addition  to  the  population  of  about  8  million  persons. 
Where  population  is  rising  at  the  rate  of  one  per  cent  annually  it  has  been 
estimated  that  a  country  must  have  real  savings  equal  to  4  per  cent  of  the 
national  income  to  maintain  per  capita  incomes.  With  a  2  per  cent  in- 
crease in  population,  the  rate  of  savings  would  have  to  reach  8  per  cent 
per  year.  Thus  some  overpopulated  countries  may  well  face  the  problem 
of  having  to  run  faster  simply  to  stand  still.  Moreover,  if  the  experience  of 


808       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

industrialized  countries  is  any  guide,  it  will  take  some  decades  before 
declining  birth  rates  significantly  reduce  population  growth.  Unless  the 
overpopulated  countries  are  able  to  accelerate  this  planned  reduction, 
they  may  face  a  serious  population  explosion. 

Even  the  above  brief  and  incomplete  discussion  indicates  that  the  un- 
derdeveloped countries  face  many  hurdles  in  their  efforts  to  industrialize. 
Many  of  these  obstacles  were  surmounted  only  gradually  by  the  western 
industrialized  countries.  Whether  the  process  can  be  telescoped  rapidly 
enough  to  satisfy  the  aspirations  of  the  underdeveloped  areas  still  remains 
to  be  seen.  In  any  case,  the  achievement  of  economic  progress  "will  make 
enormous  demands  on  intelligence  in  planning,  honesty  and  ability  in 
execution,  and  on  discipline  within  the  community."  10 


THE  CHALLENGE  OF  ECONOMIC  BACKWARDNESS 


11 


Economic  backwardness  and  mass  poverty  in  many  regions  of  the 
world  and  among  large  numbers  of  people  are  not  recent  phenomena. 
Wide  differences  in  living  standards  between  the  industrialized  countries 
of  the  West  and  the  underdeveloped  countries  of  Asia,  Africa,  and  Latin 
America  have  existed  for  a  century  or  more.  Up  until  the  last  decade  or 
so,  this  situation  had  no  significant  international  political  implications. 
The  underdeveloped  areas  played  an  important  but  largely  passive  role 
in  the  struggles  of  the  great  powers  to  acquire  territory.  They  were  valued 
largely  as  sources  of  food  and  raw  materials  to  meet  the  growing  needs  of 
the  industrial  states  and  as  markets  for  finished  manufactures.  The  indus- 
trialized countries  showed  a  minimum  concern  for  the  welfare  of  the 
underdeveloped  areas.  Although  the  latter  became  increasingly  restive 
and  resentful  of  their  role  as  "hewers  of  wood  and  drawers  of  water," 
they  were  for  the  most  part  too  weak  economically  and  politically  to  do 
much  about  it. 

Particularly  since  the  end  of  World  War  II,  the  underdeveloped  coun- 
tries have  moved  from  the  periphery  to  the  center  of  the  world  political 
arena.  Two  factors  largely  account  for  this.  On  the  one  hand,  the  political 
and  economic  control  of  the  Western  powers  over  the  less  developed 
areas  has  declined  sharply,  partly  because  of  the  weakness  of  Western 
Europe  and  partly  because  of  the  growing  strength  of  the  movement  for 
national  self-determination  and  social  justice  in  the  backward  countries. 
As  a  result,  we  have  witnessed  since  1947  the  voluntary  withdrawal  of  the 

10  Ibid.,  p.  89. 

11  For  a  fuller  treatment  of  this  subject  see  E.  Staley,  The  Future  of  Underdeveloped 
Countries  (New  York,  Harper  &  Brothers,  1954). 


THE  CHALLENGE  OF  THE  UNDERDEVELOPED  AREAS   609 

British  from  India,  Burma,  Ceylon,  and  Pakistan.  We  have  seen  the  forced 
retirement  of  the  Netherlands  from  Indonesia  and  France's  surrender  of  a 
part  of  Indochina  and  her  declaration  of  the  independence  of  Morocco 
and  Tunisia.  Britain  and  France  face  growing  political  turmoil  and  unrest 
in  certain  of  their  African  dependencies.  There  has  been  a  progressive 
weakening  of  the  political  and  economic  influence  of  the  major  industrial 
powers  in  the  Middle  East  and  to  a  much  lesser  extent  in  Latin  America. 
On  the  other  hand,  we  have  had  the  breakdown  of  the  traditional  balance- 
of -power  system  in  international  relations  and  the  polarization  of  political 
power  around  the  two  superstates,  the  United  States  and  the  U.S.S.R.  After 
a  brief  period  of  co-operation  during  and  immediately  following  World 
War  II,  relations  between  the  United  States  and  Russia  rapidly  deterio- 
rated. By  1948  the  threat  of  Communist  expansion  and  Russian  ambitions 
for  world  supremacy  became  increasingly  clear. 

Soviet  strategy  appears  to  be  gradually  to  isolate  the  United  States  by 
cutting  off  country  after  country  from  the  Free  World,  bringing  each  into 
the  Communist  camp.  While  the  Communists  have  been  willing  to  resort 
to  naked  aggression  on  a  limited  scale  to  achieve  their  aims,  as  they  did 
in  North  Korea  and  Indochina,  their  favored  weapon  has  been  internal 
subversion  and  infiltration.  Mass  propaganda,  false  promises,  threats,  and 
trained  revolutionaries  are  widely  used  by  the  Communists  to  attract  ad- 
herents to  the  Soviet  fold.  Economic  and  political  unrest  are  exploited 
wherever  they  exist.  The  Russians  made  strenuous  efforts  to  undermine 
Western  Europe  after  the  war  by  capitalizing  on  the  economic  stagnation, 
social  unrest,  and  disillusionment  which  affected  the  entire  area.  These 
attempts  were  frustrated  in  large  measure  by  the  success  of  the  United 
States'-sponsored  European  Economic  Recovery  Program.  Billions  of  dol- 
lars of  United  States  aid  were  effective  in  helping  to  rehabilitate  war- 
devastated  Western  Europe  and  in  removing  the  principal  causes  of 
economic  and  social  discontent. 

More  recently  the  threat  of  Communist  penetration  has  taken  a  new 
course.  Thwarted  in  the  more  highly  developed  industrialized  countries 
of  the  West,  the  Communists  now  appear  to  be  directing  their  main  attack 
against  the  underdeveloped  areas.  Their  efforts  already  have  succeeded 
in  bringing  into  the  Soviet  orbit  the  East  European  satellites  and  main- 
land China  with  a  combined  population  in  excess  of  700  million.  The 
menace  of  Soviet  expansion  in  the  underdeveloped  areas  probably  repre- 
sents a  much  more  serious  challenge  to  the  Free  World  than  Communist 
penetration  of  Western  Europe.  Political  and  economic  conditions  in 
many  of  the  underdeveloped  countries  are  ideal  for  Soviet  exploitation. 


610       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

The  governments  of  most  of  these  countries  are  weak  and  inexperienced. 
Poverty  and  mass  discontent  are  widespread.  Most  backward  areas  have 
had  a  long  heritage  of  political  and  economic  domination  by  the  Western 
industrialized  powers.  Consequently  they  are  extremely  suspicious  if  not 
hostile  toward  the  West.  Soviet  propaganda  plays  on  these  suspicions 
in  order  to  discredit  the  West  and  to  drive  a  wedge  between  the  independ- 
ent underdeveloped  areas  and  the  Free  World.  The  postwar  years  have 
brought  a  rising  tide  of  expectations  among  backward  peoples  for  eco- 
nomic betterment.  Millions  in  the  underdeveloped  areas  have  become 
aware  of  their  depressed  economic  status  and  are  no  longer  willing  to  sit 
back  idly  and  do  nothing  about  it.  They  are  determined  to  try  to  achieve 
higher  living  standards.  This  ferment  among  the  peoples  of  the  underde- 
veloped areas  has  been  graphically  described  by  Eugene  Black,  Presi- 
dent of  the  International  Bank  for  Reconstruction  and  Development,  as 
follows:  12 

Perhaps  the  most  powerful  single  force  shaping  the  course  of  history  in  our 
time  is  the  awakening  consciousness  of  the  underprivileged  masses  of  the  people 
that  the  conditions  of  poverty,  ill-health  and  ignorance  in  which  they  live  are 
not  preordained  and  their  deep  conviction  that  they  have  a  right  to  the  oppor- 
tunity to  earn  a  better  living  for  themselves  and  a  better  future  for  their 
children. 

The  awakening  of  the  backward  areas  was  dramatically  demonstrated 
by  the  convening  of  the  Bandung  Conference  of  Asian  and  African  States 
in  April,  1955  (cf.  Fig.  8-21,  p.  288).  The  final  communique  of  the  confer- 
ence placed  major  emphasis  on  the  urgency  of  promoting  economic  de- 
velopment in  the  Asian-African  regions. 

The  desire  of  the  underdeveloped  countries  for  economic  progress  is 
of  course  motivated  by  other  considerations  in  addition  to  the  wish  to 
improve  living  conditions.  Important  also  is  their  concern  about  security 
and  national  prestige.  Like  Japan  and  Turkey  before  them,  the  govern- 
ments of  many  underdeveloped  countries,  particularly  in  the  newly  inde- 
pendent ones,  recognize  that  political  independence  has  limited  signifi- 
cance if  they  are  too  weak  militarily  to  prevent  foreign  interference  in 
their  domestic  affairs  or  to  defend  themselves  against  external  aggression. 
Economic  progress  is  viewed  as  an  essential  step  in  the  development  of 
military  strength.  Countries  like  India  which  aspire  to  leadership  among 
Asiatic  peoples  realize  this  will  require  the  building-up  of  their  economic 
and  military  strength. 

12  Summary  Proceedings,  Fifth  Annual  Meeting  of  the  Board  of  Governors,  Wash- 
ington, D.  C,  November  30,  1950. 


THE  CHALLENGE  OF  THE  UNDERDEVELOPED  AREAS   611 

Although  to  some  extent  an  irrational  consideration,  the  prestige  factor 
also  is  significant  as  a  motive  for  economic  progress  among  underdevel- 
oped countries.  Most  backward  areas  are  extremely  sensitive  about  their 
inferior  economic  status.  They  view  economic  progress  and  in  particular 
industrialization  as  essential  if  they  are  to  gain  acceptance  and  respect 
in  the  community  of  nations.  The  preoccupation  of  the  underdeveloped 
countries  with  problems  of  economic  growth  is  strongly  reflected  in  the 
proceedings  and  discussions  within  the  United  Nations.  It  has  led  to  the 
establishment  under  United  Nations  auspices  of  special  study  groups  to 
examine  the  economic  problems  of  regional  groupings  of  countries  such 
as  the  Economic  Commission  for  Latin  America,  and  the  Economic  Com- 
mission for  Asia  and  the  Far  East.  Most  underdeveloped  countries  have 
in  recent  years  prepared  detailed  plans  to  speed  their  economic  growth 
and  have  established  special  government  agencies  to  implement  these 
plans.  Some  of  these  plans  are  soundly  conceived,  others  are  highly  vision- 
ary. In  many  cases,  however,  their  fulfillment  is  very  uncertain  because 
of  financial  limitations  as  well  as  the  many  other  serious  impediments  to 
economic  growth  which  were  described  elsewhere. 

Economic  backwardness  is  only  one  of  a  number  of  issues  which  the 
Communists  seek  to  exploit  in  the  underdeveloped  areas.  Other  sources 
of  discontent  subject  to  Communist  manipulation  include  peasant  resent- 
ment against  the  wealthy  estate  owners,  Soviet  claims  of  Western  racial 
intolerance,  and  the  anti-imperialist  theme.  Thus  while  economic  progress 
in  underdeveloped  countries  is  likely  to  reduce  the  danger  of  Communist 
penetration,  it  by  no  means  eliminates  the  risk. 

Lack  of  economic  progress  can  be  expected  to  increase  discontent 
among  the  masses  who  though  politically  inarticulate  expect  better 
things.  This  discontent  undoubtedly  will  be  exploited  by  Communist 
agents  and  their  supporters  in  an  effort  to  undermine  existing  govern- 
ments which  are  at  least  neutral  in  the  East- West  struggle  if  not  allied 
with  the  democratic  West.  Many  governments  of  underdeveloped  coun- 
tries have  been  greatly  impressed  by  the  rapid  economic  progress 
achieved  in  the  U.S.S.R.  and  its  satellites.  If  their  present  efforts  to  de- 
velop fail,  they  may  be  tempted  to  follow  the  Communist  solution.  "Under 
total  dictatorship,  the  accumulation  of  capital  is  straightforward  for,  even 
if  standards  are  low,  saving  can  be  enforced  by  starving  the  marginal 
people.  Russian  'kulaks'  yesterday,  Chinese  peasants  today,  have  been 
taught  to  pay  with  their  lives  for  the  program  of  industrialization. . . .  But 
modernization  is  achieved.  The  methods  are  there.  This  fact  constitutes 
perhaps  the  chief  attraction  of  Communism  to  backward  peoples  every- 


612        THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

where."  13  This  is  why  the  economic  backwardness  of  the  underdeveloped 
areas  now  presents  such  a  grave  challenge  to  the  Free  World.  The  threat 
of  Communist  penetration  and  even  takeover  is  of  course  not  equally 
great  in  all  underdeveloped  areas.  Most  vulnerable  would  appear  to  be 
the  countries  of  Asia  on  the  fringes  of  the  Communist  bloc.  Though  Com- 
munists are  active  in  Africa  and  Latin  America,  their  efforts  in  these 
regions  pose  less  of  a  problem  for  the  West.  Nonetheless  these  regions 
do  show  considerable  political  and  social  instability  in  part  at  least 
because  of  unsatisfactory  economic  conditions.  Communist-inspired  or 
not,  this  growing  unrest  in  the  underdeveloped  areas  is  a  threat  to  the 
security  of  the  Free  World. 


THE  INTERESTS  OF  THE  FREE  WORLD  IN  THE 
UNDERDEVELOPED  AREAS 

Strategic.  It  is  of  great  importance  for  the  security  and  economic  wel- 
fare of  the  Free  World  that  the  presently  uncommitted  underdeveloped 
areas  do  not  fall  into  the  Soviet  camp.  Many  underdeveloped  areas  oc- 
cupy highly  strategic  geographical  positions  across  lines  of  communication 
important  to  the  Free  World  both  in  peace  and  in  war.  The  Suez  Canal 
in  the  Middle  East,  which  links  the  eastern  Mediterranean  and  the  Indian 
Ocean,  is  a  case  in  point.  Underdeveloped  areas  provide  bases  which  are 
essential  links  in  the  West's  air  offensive  and  defensive  systems.  They  are 
significant  as  assembly  areas  and  supply  bases  for  troops  and  materiel  in 
time  of  war  and  as  fueling  stations  for  naval  and  cargo  vessels.  Control 
of  these  areas  by  unfriendly  powers  would  greatly  weaken  the  defensive 
and  offensive  military  capabilities  of  the  West. 

The  underdeveloped  areas  are  a  vast  source  of  manpower  which  if 
effectively  mobilized  could  greatly  increase  the  military  capabilities  of 
the  Communist  bloc.  Such  areas  now  outside  the  Soviet  orbit  have  a 
population  of  over  one  billion  persons.  Of  this  number  over  700  million 
live  on  the  periphery  of  the  Communist  sphere  in  the  Middle  East  and  in 
South  and  Southeast  Asia.  These  are  the  regions  now  most  vulnerable  to 
Communist  subversion.  If  they  were  to  go  Communist,  the  population  of 
the  Soviet  bloc  would  be  almost  doubled,  thus  giving  the  bloc  an  over- 
whelming superiority  over  the  West  in  manpower. 

Sheer  numbers  alone  obviously  do  not  make  for  economic  and  military 

13  B.  Ward,  "One  Answer  to  the  Challenge  of  Africa,"  New  York  Times  Magazine, 
October  31,  1944. 


THE  CHALLENGE  OF  THE  UNDERDEVELOPED  AREAS   613 

power.  If  they  did,  many  underdeveloped  countries  would  be  first-rate 
powers.  The  quality  and  leadership  of  the  population  is  more  important 
than  numbers.  The  populations  of  the  underdeveloped  areas  are  deficient 
in  health,  literacy,  and  in  technical  skills.  They  frequently  lack  strong 
and  effective  leadership.  However,  the  recent  experiences  of  the  United 
Nations  forces  in  Korea,  and  of  the  French  in  Indochina  demonstrate  that 
Communist  leaders  can  mobilize  these  peoples  into  effective  fighting 
forces  within  the  brief  period  of  a  few  years.  Even  in  their  present  stage 
of  economic  development  the  underdeveloped  countries,  particularly  in 
Asia,  thus  have  major  military  potentialities. 

Economic.  The  United  States  and  the  other  industrialized  countries  of 
the  Free  World  are  heavily  dependent  on  the  underdeveloped  areas  for 
raw  materials  and  this  dependence  is  expected  to  increase  rapidly.  Ac- 
cording to  the  President's  Materials  Policy  Commission,  the  United  States 
drew  on  foreign  sources  for  9  per  cent  of  its  raw  material  needs  in  1950. 
The  corresponding  figure  for  other  Free  World  industrialized  countries 
is  considerably  higher.  Most  of  these  raw  materials  came  from  the  under- 
developed areas.  By  1975,  the  President's  Commission  estimates  that  im- 
ported raw  materials  will  represent  from  15  to  25  per  cent  of  United 
States'  requirements  and  a  much  higher  proportion  of  Japan's  and  West- 
ern Europe's.  Many  of  these  raw  material  imports  are  items  of  consider- 
able strategic  importance.  According  to  the  International  Development 
Advisory  Board,  "Of  all  of  the  imported  items  which  are  of  sufficient 
military  importance  to  be  included  in  our  stockpiles,  73  per  cent  are 
drawn  from  these  areas  [underdeveloped]."  14  The  Board  concluded  that 
"The  loss  of  any  of  these  materials  through  aggression,  subversion  or  so- 
cial collapse,  would  be  the  equivalent  of  a  grave  military  set-back."  15 

The  underdeveloped  areas  are  the  major  trading  partners  of  the  indus- 
trialized countries  of  the  West.  In  the  years  1948  to  1950,  approximately 
half  of  the  foreign  trade  of  the  United  States  was  with  the  underdeveloped 
regions.  For  Western  European  countries,  the  percentage  was  almost  70 
per  cent  in  1950. 16  This  trade,  by  promoting  international  economic  spe- 
cialization and  division  of  labor,  has  contributed  materially  to  raising 
living  standards  in  both  the  industrialized  and  the  underdeveloped  coun- 
tries. It  is  essential  for  the  economic  viability  of  countries  like  Japan  and 
the  United  Kingdom,  which  are  particularly  dependent  on  foreign  trade. 

The  industrialized  countries  have  other  important  economic  interests 

14  Partners  in  Progress,  a  Report  to  the  President  by  the  International  Development 
Advisory  Board,  March,  1951,  p.  5. 

15  Ibid.,  p.  46. 

16  Ibid.,  pp.  6-7. 


614       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

in  the  underdeveloped  countries.  Among  these  are  very  substantial  invest- 
ments. The  return  on  these  investments  finances  a  large  proportion  of  the 
traditional  import  deficits  of  countries  like  the  United  Kingdom  or  the 
Netherlands.  The  underdeveloped  areas  are  an  important  source  of  earn- 
ings for  services  like  shipping,  insurance,  and  banking.  They  earn  scarce 
dollars  for  European  affiliates  and  provide  many  commodities  which 
otherwise  would  have  to  be  purchased  for  dollars.  They  provide  all  sorts 
of  special  and  valuable  economic  advantages  to  individual  Western  coun- 
tries such  as  tariff  preferences  and  monopoly  rights  to  exploit  mineral 
resources. 

Communist  expansion  in  underdeveloped  countries  typically  has  resulted 
in  a  progressive  decline  in  the  penetrated  area's  economic  relations  with  the 
West.  Foreign  investments  are  expropriated  without  compensation  to  the 
rightful  owners.  Thus  the  Chinese  Communists  took  over  an  estimated 
billion  dollars  in  properties  belonging  to  United  Kingdom  nationals. 
Trade  with  the  Free  World  contracts  sharply.17  In  1951,  the  volume  of 
Western  Europe's  trade  with  the  European  satellites,  including  East  Ger- 
many, was  only  about  20  per  cent  of  prewar.  Trade  between  Red  China 
and  the  Free  World  also  has  declined  very  significantly  since  the  Com- 
munist takeover.  Trade  of  the  satellites  with  each  other  and  with  the 
Soviet  Union,  on  the  other  hand,  has  shown  a  more  than  corresponding 
increase.  Before  World  War  II  trade  between  the  U.S.S.R.  and  the  eastern 
European  countries  and  China  was  almost  nonexistent,  and  between  the 
satellites  themselves  was  of  very  limited  significance.  By  1951,  however, 
it  is  estimated  that  intra-bloc  trade  accounted  for  80  per  cent  of  total-bloc 
trade.18  This  represents  a  tenfold  increase  in  the  volume  of  intra-bloc 
trade. 

Part  of  the  decline  in  trade  between  the  West  and  the  Communist  bloc, 
and  in  particular  with  Communist  China,  has  resulted  from  the  applica- 
tion of  Western  security  controls.  In  large  measure,  however,  it  is  the 
result  of  deliberate  Soviet  policy.  Soviet  foreign  trade  policy  is  governed 
more  by  security  than  by  economic  considerations.  The  Russians  seek  to 
maximize  intra-bloc  trade  and  to  reduce  dependence  on  outside  supplies 
to  a  minimum.  This  policy  of  economic  autarchy  is  designed  to  limit  the 
vulnerability  of  the  Soviet  bloc  to  the  cutting  off  of  foreign  sources  of 
supply  in  the  event  of  war. 

Practical  considerations  necessarily  have  limited  and  will  probably  con- 

17  Economic    Bulletin    for    Europe,    Economic    Commission    for    Europe,    Second 
Quarter,  1952. 
i8  Ibid, 


THE  CHALLENGE  OF  THE  UNDERDEVELOPED  AREAS       615 

tinue  to  limit  the  extent  and  speed  with  which  satellite  economies  are  inte- 
grated into  the  Soviet  bloc.  One  very  important  consideration  is  the  fact 
that  many  underdeveloped  areas  have  supplies  available  for  export  sub- 
stantially in  excess  of  the  bloc's  immediate  requirements.  For  example, 
the  bloc  could  not  use  all  of  Iran's  oil  in  the  foreseeable  future  and  the 
same  would  be  true  for  Malayan  rubber.  At  the  same  time,  the  bloc's  ca- 
pabilities for  supplying  the  machinery  and  equipment  required  to  pro- 
mote the  economic  development  of  the  backward  areas  is  limited.  Under 
these  circumstances,  continued  trade  with  the  West  would  still  be  ad- 
vantageous. 

Such  Communist-controlled  supplies,  however,  would  be  highly  unre- 
liable. They  could  be  cut  off  at  any  time  for  political  or  other  reasons  or 
might  be  used  as  a  lever  to  force  political  concessions.  They  might  be 
supplied  at  relatively  unfavorable  terms  to  Western  buyers.  Soviet  trade 
is  conducted  through  state  trading  corporations  and  their  bargaining 
power  is  generally  much  stronger  than  that  of  private  individual  traders 
in  the  West. 

So  far  the  over-all  adverse  economic  effects  on  the  West  of  Communist 
expansion  in  the  underdeveloped  areas  has  been  fairly  moderate.  Certain 
countries  have  been  harder  hit  than  others.  Japan  is  an  example  of  a 
country  whose  trading  position  has  been  most  seriously  affected  by  Com- 
munist expansion.  Before  the  war  more  than  30  per  cent  of  Japan's  trade 
was  with  the  Chinese  mainland  and  North  Korea.  By  1954  this  was  re- 
duced to  a  trickle.  Loss  of  China  both  as  a  source  of  raw  materials  and 
as  a  market  for  exports  is  an  important  obstacle,  though  by  no  means  the 
only  one,  to  Japan's  becoming  self-supporting.  Moreover,  the  Japanese 
economy  is  particularly  vulnerable  to  any  further  Communist  expansion 
in  the  Far  East.  At  the  present  time  roughly  35  per  cent  of  Japan's  foreign 
trade  is  with  South  and  Southeast  Asia  as  against  20  per  cent  prewar.  If 
this  region  fell  into  the  Communist  bloc,  Japan  would  find  it  almost  im- 
possible to  achieve  economic  self-support  except  by  coming  to  terms  with 
the  Communists. 

The  Soviet  economy  probably  has  gained  more  than  the  West  has  lost 
as  a  result  of  the  expansion  of  the  Communist  orbit.  There  is  considerable 
evidence  to  indicate  Russian  exploitation  of  the  satellites.  Moreover,  if 
the  satellite  economies  are  able  to  maintain  anything  like  the  high  rates 
of  growth  they  claim  to  have  achieved  under  the  Communists,  the  result 
would  be  a  considerable  over-all  strengthening  of  the  bloc  economy  rela- 
tive to  the  West.  According  to  official  Communist  statistics,  rates  of  eco- 
nomic growth  in  the  eastern  European  satellites  have  averaged  10  to  20 


616       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

per  cent  a  year  during  the  1950's.19  This  compares  with  quite  low  rates 
of  growth  in  many  underdeveloped  regions  outside  of  Latin  America. 
Official  Chinese  figures  claim  that  15  per  cent  of  the  gross  national  prod- 
uct was  budgeted  for  investment  in  1954.  If  true,  this  would  give  China 
a  level  of  investment  almost  twice  that  of  neighboring  South  and  South- 
east Asia  which  has  roughly  the  same  total  population.  In  the  absence  of 
a  rapid  speeding  up  of  economic  growth  in  South  and  Southeast  Asia, 
China  could  in  the  foreseeable  future  become  the  dominant  economic 
power  in  the  Far  East.20 

Regardless  of  the  outcome  of  political  trends  in  the  underdeveloped 
regions,  their  efforts  to  develop  more  rapidly  are  creating  and  will  con- 
tinue to  create  major  problems  of  economic  adjustment  for  the  industrial- 
ized countries.  These  problems  largely  derive  from  the  determination  of 
the  underdeveloped  areas  to  diversify  their  economies  and  to  reduce 
their  dependence  on  exports  of  a  few  primary  products.  This  distrust  of 
relying  on  production  of  primary  products  stems  in  part  from  the  drastic 
deflation  of  raw  material  prices  during  the  1930's  and  also  the  tendency 
of  the  underdeveloped  countries  to  associate  raw-materials  production 
with  colonialism  and  foreign  domination.  As  a  first  step  in  this  process  of 
diversification,  almost  all  underdeveloped  countries  are  attempting  to 
meet  at  least  some  part  of  their  requirements  for  the  simpler  types  of 
manufactures  such  as  textiles,  shoes,  soap,  matches,  and  other  consumer 
goods.  This  has  cut  sharply  into  the  markets  of  the  large  traditional  ex- 
porters of  consumer  goods  like  the  United  Kingdom  and  Japan.  It  has 
necessitated  significant  and  costly  shifts  in  the  structure  of  their  export 
industries  to  accommodate  the  reduced  relative  importance  of  consumer- 
goods  exports.  In  some  instances,  notably  India,  underdeveloped  coun- 
tries since  the  war  have  become  major  competitors  of  industrialized 
countries  for  export  markets.  In  1950  India,  with  exports  of  118  thousand 
tons  of  cotton  cloth,  was  the  world's  largest  exporter,  exceeding  Japan 
and  the  United  Kingdom  by  a  considerable  margin.  The  rise  of  India  as 
an  important  and  efficient  textile  producer  partly  explains  why  Japan's 
exports  of  cotton  goods  are  only  40  per  cent  of  prewar.  Today  we  find 
Lancashire,  which  rose  to  eminence  as  the  world's  leading  textile  center 
largely  on  the  basis  of  its  markets  in  the  underdeveloped  areas,  asking  the 
British  Government  for  tariff  protection  against  Indian  textiles. 

The  measures  taken  by  the  underdeveloped  countries  to  industrialize 
and  diversify  their  economies  are  partly  responsible  for  the  fact  that  the 

19  United  Nations,  Economic  Survey  of  Europe  in  1953  (Geneva,  1954). 

20  See  Chapter  15,  pp.  509-518. 


THE  CHALLENGE  OF  THE  UNDERDEVELOPED  AREAS   617 

industrialized  countries  are  unable  to  import  food  and  raw  materials  on 
as  favorable  terms  as  before  the  war.  A  number  of  countries  deliberately 
have  pursued  economic  policies  designed  to  encourage  the  expansion  of 
industry  at  the  expense  of  primary  production.  Often  the  favored  indus- 
tries are  impractical  and  are  able  to  withstand  foreign  competition  only 
under  an  umbrella  of  high  protective  tariffs.  Argentina  is  one  of  the  most 
notable  examples  of  a  country  which  pursued  this  type  of  policy  after 
World  War  II.  The  result  was  a  sharp  decline  in  export  availabilities  and 
higher  prices  for  foodstuffs  to  Argentina's  traditional  market,  the  United 
Kingdom.  Subsequently  Argentina  reversed  its  shortsighted  policy  of  neg- 
lecting agriculture  when  the  decline  in  its  export  earnings  threatened  to 
jeopardize  its  entire  development  program.  Although  such  extreme  poli- 
cies favoring  industrialization  have  been  abandoned  by  most  underdevel- 
oped areas,  the  distrust  of  primary  production  persists. 

Even  where  the  advantages  of  promoting  primary  production  are  rec- 
ognized, many  obstacles  are  placed  in  the  way  of  expanding  output  by 
the  underdeveloped  countries.  These  include  various  prohibitions  and 
limitations  imposed  on  foreign  investors,  such  as  restrictions  on  the  con- 
vertibility of  capital  and  earnings  or  the  requirement  of  majority  local 
participation  in  the  ownership  and  management.  Then  there  is  the  fre- 
quent threat  of  nationalization  or  expropriation  without  adequate  com- 
pensation. Many  underdeveloped  countries  are  unwilling  to  allow  foreign 
capital  to  participate  in  the  exploitation  of  their  natural  resources  even 
though  they  lack  the  capital  and  technical  know-how  to  do  it  themselves. 
Where  foreign  capital  is  welcomed,  the  underdeveloped  areas  are  insist- 
ing on  a  larger  share  of  the  profits  and  are  demanding  more  adequate 
compensation  for  local  labor.  All  of  these  factors,  combined  with  the  fact 
that  the  best  and  most  accessible  resources  are  being  consumed,  suggest 
that  primary  products  will  be  available  from  the  underdeveloped  areas 
on  progressively  less  favorable  terms. 

ECONOMIC  AID  IN  THE  STRUGGLE  FOR  THE 
UNDERDEVELOPED  AREAS 

Since  World  War  II  the  industrialized  countries  of  the  West  and  in 
particular  the  United  States  have  shown  a  growing  concern  about  the 
economic  problems  of  the  underdeveloped  areas.  In  part  this  interest  is 
based  on  humanitarian  considerations  and  in  part  on  a  recognition  that 
the  material  well-being  of  the  advanced  countries  is  heavily  dependent 
on  the  economic  health  of  the  underdeveloped  countries.  More  impor- 


618       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

tantly,  however,  it  reflects  concern  about  the  security  of  the  Free  World. 
Poverty  and  lack  of  economic  progress  are  recognized  as  important  causes 
of  the  growing  political  instability  and  social  unrest  in  the  underdevel- 
oped areas  making  them  fertile  breeding  places  for  Communist  subver- 
sion. 

This  view  of  the  relationship  between  economic  development  and  sub- 
version has  found  widespread  expression  in  official  and  semi-official 
documents  dealing  with  United  States  foreign  economic  policy.  Thus  the 
International  Development  Board  in  its  report  to  the  President  states:  21 
"To  achieve  lasting  peace,  security,  and  well-being  in  the  world  we  must 
join  forces  in  an  economic  offensive  to  root  out  hunger,  poverty,  illiteracy 
and  disease.  The  issue  really  is  one  of  economic  development  versus  eco- 
nomic subversion.  Soviet  imperialism  is  seeking  to  chop  off  country  after 
country,  to  leave  us  in  isolation." 

One  of  the  principal  weapons  employed  by  the  West  to  counter  the 
danger  of  political  instability  and  Communist  subversion  in  the  under- 
developed areas  has  been  economic  and  military  aid.  Here  because  of  its 
much  greater  industrial  capabilities  the  West  enjoys  a  strong  advantage 
over  the  U.S.S.R.  Most  of  the  aid  extended  by  the  West  has  been  provided 
by  the  United  States.  The  economies  of  the  other  major  industrial  powers 
have  been  too  weak  since  the  war  to  support  contributions  on  anything 
like  the  U.S.  scale.  Nonetheless  aid  from  other  countries  has  not  been 
inconsequential.  Under  its  Colonial  Development  and  Welfare  Act,  the 
United  Kingdom  provided  140  million  pounds  sterling  from  1945  to  1954 
to  assist  in  colonial  development.  An  additional  80  million  pounds  is  to 
be  provided  for  the  next  5  years.  In  addition,  the  European  metropoles, 
particularly  the  United  Kingdom,  France,  and  Belgium,  have  been  mak- 
ing sizable  investments  in  their  colonies  to  promote  economic  growth.  To 
an  important  extent  these  investments  were  made  possible  by  direct  U.S. 
aid  to  Europe. 

During  the  period  July  1,  1945  to  June  30,  1954,  direct  U.S.  economic 
aid  to  the  underdeveloped  areas  in  the  form  of  grants  and  credits  ex- 
ceeded $5  billion  ( see  Table  19-3 ) .  With  the  recovery  of  Western  Europe, 
economic  aid  to  the  underdeveloped  areas  has  represented  an  increasing 
share  of  total  aid.  In  1953  U.S.  economic  aid  to  the  underdeveloped 
areas  of  roughly  $1.2  billion  represented  almost  half  of  all  U.S.  economic 
aid.  In  1955  to  1956  it  is  estimated  the  proportion  will  be  more  than  two- 
thirds. 

The  U.S.S.R.  by  contrast  appears  to  have  extended  relatively  limited 

21  Partners  in  Progress  (Washington,  D.  C,  March,  1951). 


THE  CHALLENGE  OF  THE  UNDERDEVELOPED  AREAS       619 


assistance  to  the  underdeveloped  countries,  except  to  China,  and  its  Euro- 
pean satellites  and  much  of  this  has  been  military  aid.  It  was  not  until 
1953  that  the  U.S.S.R.  made  a  contribution  of  $1  million  to  the  United 
Nations  technical  assistance  program.  More  recently,  however,  there  have 
been  signs  that  the  U.S.S.R.  may  step-up  its  economic  offensive.  The  most 
notable  example  in  this  campaign  to  date  has  been  Soviet  penetration  of 
Afghanistan.  A  reported  500  Russian  technicians  were  in  Afghanistan  in 
1955  helping  in  the  country's  economic  development.22  When  Pakistan 
closed  its  Afghan  border  and  imposed  an  economic  blockade  against 
Afghanistan  as  a  result  of  an  incident  in  March  1955  arising  out  of  the 
Pushtunistan  dispute,  the  Russians  were  quick  to  capitalize  on  the  situa- 
tion. They  offered  the  Afghans  an  alternate  transit  route  to  the  Pakistan 
Port  of  Karachi  through  Soviet  territory.  An  agreement  was  signed  au- 
thorizing the  landing  of  Afghan  imports  at  Black  Sea  ports  and  their  car- 
riage by  rail  at  subsidized  rates  to  the  Soviet-Afghan  border.  Early  in 
1955  the  Soviet  Union  signed  an  agreement  to  build  a  million-ton  steel 
plant  for  India  on  very  favorable  terms.  In  addition  to  supplying  arms  to 
Egypt  in  1955  the  Russians  also  said  they  were  willing  to  help  finance 
the  High  dam  on  the  Aswam,  a  10  year  $1,300  million  project.  It  also  is 
increasing  its  efforts  to  arrange  bilateral  trade  agreements  with  the  under- 
developed areas  purchasing  products  like  Egyptian  cotton  or  Burmese 
rice  which  in  1955  were  in  serious  oversupply.  In  some  instances  it  has 
offered  to  extend  long-term  credits.  With  its  growing  industrial  strength 
the  U.S.S.R.  could  become  a  formidable  competitor  against  the  West  in 
an  economic  offensive  to  gain  political  capital  among  the  underdeveloped 
regions. 

TABLE  19-3 

U.  S.  Non-Military  Grants  and  Credits  to  Underdeveloped  Areas 
July  1,  1945  Through  June  30,  1954  •  * 


AREA 

TOTAL 

NET  GRANTS 

NET  CREDITS 

Near  East  and  Africa 

South  Asia 

Southeast  Asia 

Korea  and  Nationalist  China 

Latin  America 

$    860 

389 

1,173 

2,035 

906 

$5,363 

$    598 

123 

962 

1,907 

207 

$3,797 

$    262 
266 
211 
128 
699 

Total 

$1,566 

a  In  millions. 

*  Excludes  aid  given  dependent  areas  through  United  States  grants  or  loans  to  the  mother  countries. 
Also  excludes  aid  by  the  United  States  through  international  organizations.  United  States  Department  of 
Commerce,  Foreign  Grants  and  Credit  by  the  United  States  Government,  June,  1954. 

22  New  York  Times,  November  15,  1955. 


620        THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

Point  Four.  Assisting  the  economic  development  of  the  underdeveloped 
areas  can  be  said  to  have  become  a  definite  part  of  United  States  foreign 
economic  policy  with  the  adoption  of  the  so-called  Point  IV  program  in 
1950.  The  name  Point  IV  derives  from  the  famous  fourth  point  of  Presi- 
dent Truman's  inaugural  address  of  January  20,  1949,  in  which  he  called 
for  "a  bold  new  program  for  making  the  benefits  of  our  scientific  advances 
and  industrial  progress  available  for  the  improvement  and  growth  of 
underdeveloped  areas." 

This  proposal  resulted  in  the  Act  for  International  Development  which 
authorized  technical  assistance  programs  to  the  underdeveloped  areas 
under  both  bilateral  and  United  Nations  multilateral  arrangements. 

Point  IV  is  essentially  a  long-range  program  intended  to  lay  the  basis 
for  gradual  economic  and  social  progress  in  the  underdeveloped  areas. 
Its  main  emphasis  is  on  the  supplying  of  basic  technological  and  scientific 
services  and  the  training  of  foreign  nationals  rather  than  on  the  provision 
of  capital.  Capital  goods  are  a  small  fraction  of  the  technical  services 
component.  The  expectation  is  to  gradually  create  a  favorable  atmosphere 
for  private  investment. 

The  United  States  bilateral  technical  assistance  program  is  considerably 
larger  than  the  United  Nations  multilateral  program.  United  States  ap- 
propriations for  technical  assistance  in  the  fiscal  year  1954  amounted  to 
$118  million.  This  compares  with  $40  to  50  million  at  the  disposal  of  the 
United  Nations  and  its  specialized  agencies.  In  August,  1953,  over  1,500 
permanent  American  technicians  and  several  hundred  local-contract  and 
temporary  technicians  were  serving  abroad  under  United  States  bilateral 
programs.  In  addition,  almost  1,500  awards  had  been  made  to  foreign 
trainees.  This  compares  with  approximately  1000  experts  and  1375  trainee 
awards  under  the  United  Nations  program.23 

Efforts  in  the  field  of  technical  assistance  have  concentrated  on  agri- 
culture, health,  education,  public  administration,  and  resource  develop- 
ment. Remarkable  results  have  been  achieved  in  many  of  these  vital  areas. 
In  some  countries,  malaria  has  been  eliminated  and  infant  mortality 
sharply  reduced.  In  others,  improved  agricultural  methods  have  brought 
significant  increases  in  yields.  At  the  same  time,  however,  the  gains  from 
technical  assistance  have  given  rise  to  some  serious  new  problems.  Im- 
proved farming  methods  have  released  agricultural  workers  for  industrial 
employment  where  opportunities  in  industry  are  still  lacking.  Or  again, 
reduced  death  rates  have  aggravated  the  problem  of  population  pressure. 

23  Commission  on  Foreign  Economic  Policy,  Staff  Paper  (Washington,  D.  C, 
February,  1954),  p.  7<* 


THE  CHALLENGE  OF  THE  UNDERDEVELOPED  AREAS       621 

Probably  the  chief  criticism  levelled  at  the  program  is  that  it  can  be 
expected  to  achieve  results  only  very  slowly;  too  slowly  perhaps  in  the 
critical  areas  most  vulnerable  to  Soviet  expansion.  Economic  development 
requires  capital  as  well  as  technical  know-how  if  advantage  is  to  be  taken 
of  the  new  knowledge.  This  capital  has  not  yet  been  forthcoming  in  ade- 
quate amounts  from  private  sources.  The  problem  has  been  met  to  a 
limited  extent  in  the  United  States  by  special  assistance  programs  which 
depart  from  the  philosophy  of  Point  IV.  The  International  Bank  for  Re- 
construction and  Development  as  described  below  also  has  made  a  contri- 
bution to  the  capital  needs  of  the  underdeveloped  areas.  Although  the 
technical  assistance  programs  have  won  many  friends  for  the  West,  they 
generally  have  not  lived  up  to  the  expectations  of  the  underdeveloped 
areas  for  outside  aid. 

The  International  Bank  for  Reconstruction  and  Development.  The 
International  Bank  was  established  primarily  for  the  purpose  of  assisting 
"its  member  countries  to  raise  production  levels  and  living  standards  by 
helping  to  finance  long-term  productive  projects,  by  providing  technical 
advice  and  by  stimulating  international  investment  from  other  sources."  24 
Of  its  57  members,  39  are  in  the  underdeveloped  category.  Although 
membership  is  open  to  all  countries  no  Soviet-bloc  country  now  belongs 
and  no  loans  have  been  extended  outside  the  Free  World. 

Since  the  start  of  its  operations  in  1946  until  July,  1954,  the  Bank  has 
loaned  almost  $1  billion  to  the  underdeveloped  countries.  Roughly  half 
went  to  Latin  America,  one-quarter  to  South  and  Southeast  Asia,  and  the 
remainder  to  Africa  and  the  Middle  East.  Most  of  the  loans  went  to  fi- 
nance vital  services,  such  as  transportation,  electric  power,  telecommuni- 
cations, and  irrigation,  which  have  not  attracted  adequate  private  capital. 
In  addition,  Bank  technicians  have  furnished  a  number  of  underdevel- 
oped countries  with  valuable  assistance  in  preparing  development  proj- 
ects and  programs.  Although  the  contribution  of  the  International  Bank 
to  the  underdeveloped  areas  has  been  considerably  more  significant  than 
the  total  amount  of  loans  extended  suggests,  it  has  not  satisfied  their  de- 
sire for  external  loans.  In  general  the  underdeveloped  areas  feel  that  the 
loan  requirements  of  the  Bank  are  too  rigid.  They  have  campaigned  for 
the  creation  of  subsidiary  international  loan  agencies  with  lower  stand- 
ards. 

Atoms-for-Peace.  Few  proposals  in  recent  years  have  done  more  to  fire 
the  hopes  of  the  underdeveloped  areas  for  accelerated  economic  growth 

24  International  Bank  For  Reconstruction  and  Development,  1946-53  (Baltimore, 
1954). 


622       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

than  President  Eisenhower's  dramatic  atoms-for-peace  plan  laid  before 
the  United  Nations  on  December  8,  1953.  As  an  outgrowth  of  this  pro- 
posal, steps  are  being  taken  to  establish  an  International  Atomic  Energy 
Agency,  and  the  United  Nations  in  the  meantime  invited  84  nations  to 
participate  in  an  international  conference  on  the  peaceful  uses  of  atomic 
energy  at  Geneva  in  August,  1955.  Atoms-for-peace  has  been  widely  in- 
terpreted as  a  simple  prescription  for  the  economic  difficulties  of  the 
underdeveloped  areas.  Visions  have  been  conjured  up  of  a  vast  source  of 
cheap  electric  power  which  will  usher  in  a  new  era  of  economic  growth 
in  the  underdeveloped  areas. 

Such  extravagant  expectations  are  hardly  warranted  for  the  foreseeable 
future.  In  the  first  place  the  President's  proposal  is  necessarily  limited  in 
its  scope.  It  does  not  provide  for  large  atomic  power  plants.  The  120  kilo- 
grams of  fissionable  material  which  is  being  contributed  to  the  program 
by  the  United  States  and  the  United  Kingdom  would  not  fuel  one  large 
power  plant.  The  plan  by  and  large  calls  for  an  exchange  of  training 
facilities  and  information  and  the  use  of  radioactive  by-products  of  atomic 
fission  in  agriculture,  industry,  and  medicine.  The  fissionable  materials 
contributed  by  the  participating  countries  will  be  used  to  fuel  small  re- 
search reactors.  Thus  the  program  is  intended  primarily  to  train  personnel 
and  promote  applied  research  in  the  peaceful  uses  of  atomic  energy.  This 
is  certainly  a  requisite  first  step  for  virtually  all  underdeveloped  countries 
which  have  few  or  no  qualified  personnel  and  no  technical  facilities  for 
handling  fissionable  materials. 

In  the  second  place,  and  more  important  for  the  underdeveloped  areas, 
are  the  limitations  which  economic  considerations  are  likely  to  impose  on 
the  peaceful  applications  of  atomic  energy.  It  is  now  technically  feasible 
to  construct  electric  power  plants  fueled  with  fissionable  materials.  How- 
ever, such  power  is  high  cost  and  appears  likely  to  remain  so  over  the 
next  decade  or  so.  Any  cost  advantage  which  nuclear  power  is  to  enjoy 
over  conventional  power  must  derive  from  savings  in  fuel  costs.  Fixed 
costs  of  plant  and  equipment  for  nuclear  power  plants  are  expected  to 
run  50  per  cent  higher  than  for  conventional  plants,  and  operating  and 
maintenance  costs  may  be  twice  as  high.  Lower  fuel  costs  alone  cannot 
result  in  drastic  reductions  in  electricity  costs.  Fuel  costs  in  modern  ther- 
mal plants  in  the  United  States,  for  example,  account  for  at  most  one-half 
of  electric  power  generating  costs  and  only  about  one-fifth  of  the  average 
price  paid  by  consumers. 

The  outlook  for  the  next  decade  or  two,  therefore,  is  that  nuclear  power 
plants  will  be  competitive  only  with  conventional  thermal  plants  burning 


THE  CHALLENGE  OF  THE  UNDERDEVELOPED  AREAS       623 

relatively  high-cost  coal  or  petroleum.  They  will  not  be  competitive  with 
most  hydro-electric  plants  now  in  existence  or  with  plants  which  can  be 
built  on  fairly  favorable  sites.  The  latter  fact  will  limit  the  economic  use 
of  nuclear  power  plants  in  underdeveloped  areas  for  some  time  to  come. 
Most  underdeveloped  countries  with  growing  power  requirements  still 
possess  substantial  unexploited  hydraulic  resources  capable  of  producing 
very  low  cost  power.  A  major  reason  for  the  failure  of  power  supply  to 
keep  pace  with  requirements  in  a  number  of  underdeveloped  countries 
is  the  shortage  of  capital.  The  much  higher  capital  costs  of  nuclear  power 
plants  would  therefore  be  a  deterrent  to  the  introduction  of  nuclear  power 
even  in  areas  handicapped  by  high  fuel  costs.  The  problem  of  size  is  also 
relevant.  The  demand  for  power  in  underdeveloped  regions  frequently 
does  not  warrant  the  construction  of  large  power  stations.  While  atomic 
power  plants  are  flexible  as  regards  size,  the  smaller  they  are  the  less 
economical  they  become. 

The  above  considerations  are  expected  to  limit  the  use  of  atomic  power 
plants  in  backward  areas  to  regions  which  lack  cheap  local  fuel  and  are 
remote  from  good  hydro-electric  sites.  However,  even  if  technological 
progress  permits  the  construction  of  nuclear  power  reactors  at  substan- 
tially lower  costs  than  now  anticipated,  the  resultant  power  savings  will 
not  be  a  major  stimulus  to  economic  growth.  The  reason  for  this  is  simply 
that  power  represents  a  relatively  small  share  of  the  total  cost  of  most 
industries.  In  the  United  States  the  cost  of  electricity  represented  only 
1.7  per  cent  of  the  value  added  by  manufactures  for  all  industry  in  1947. 
For  a  number  of  industry  groups  the  ratio  was  between  2  and  4  per  cent. 
Electric  power  is  an  important  cost  factor  primarily  in  such  industries  as 
aluminum,  ferro-alloys,  and  chemicals. 

This  is  not  to  minimize  the  significance  of  atomic  power  for  the  under- 
developed areas.  World  energy  consumption  is  making  rapid  inroads  into 
the  world's  reserves  of  coal,  petroleum,  and  natural  gas.  As  lower  cost 
reserves  are  exhausted,  fuel  costs  can  be  expected  to  gradually  rise.  Con- 
sequently, fissionable  materials  are  likely  to  become  of  increasing  impor- 
tance over  the  long  run  as  a  source  of  energy.  Over  the  short  run,  the 
greatest  benefits  to  be  derived  by  the  underdeveloped  areas  from  atoms- 
for-peace  may  well  result  from  developments  in  the  use  of  radio-active 
isotopes  in  industry,  medicine,  and  agriculture. 


CHAPTER 


20 


Southwest  Asia 


Southwest  Asia  (also  called  the  Middle  or  Near  East)  is  an  area  of  very 
limited  over-all  economic  capabilities.  It  is  nonetheless  a  region  of  great 
economic  and  strategic  importance  to  the  Free  World  by  virtue  of  its  vast 
low-cost  oil  reserves  and  its  geographic  location.  Linking  three  continents, 
Southwest  Asia  stands  astride  vital  air  and  water  routes  connecting  Eu- 
rope, Asia,  and  Africa.  It  controls  two  of  the  most  vital  water  links  in  the 
world:  the  Straits  connecting  the  landlocked  Black  Sea  and  the  Mediter- 
ranean, and  the  Suez  Canal  joining  the  Mediterranean  and  the  Indian 
Ocean.  All  through  history  this  crossroads  of  the  world  has  been  a  key 
factor  in  the  strategic  calculations  of  the  major  powers.'  It  was  a  pivotal 
area  in  the  defense  of  India  and  Africa  in  World  War  II.  As  a  critical 
buffer  zone  between  Europe  and  Africa  on  the  one  hand  and  the  U.S.S.R. 
on  the  other,  Southwest  Asia  is  now  of  major  strategic  importance  to  the 
defensive  system  of  the  West.  At  the  same  time,  much  of  the  area  is  sub- 
ject to  serious  social,  political,  and  economic  unrest.  There  are  few  stable 
governments  in  Southwest  Asia  capable  of  controlling  the  rising  tide  of 
nationalism  and  revolt  against  economic  oppression.  Arab-Israeli  relations 
and  inter-Arab  feuds  are  a  constant  threat  to  the  stability  of  the  area.  The 
Israel-Arab  conflict  has  created  a  critical  refugee  problem.  The  recent 
Soviet  sale  of  arms  to  Egypt  has  created  a  new  challenge.  All  of  these 
developments  taken  together  constitute  a  serious  danger  to  the  position  of 
the  Free  World  in  this  area. 


624 


SOUTHWEST  ASIA 


625 


AREA  AND  POPULATION 

As  defined  here,  Southwest  Asia  comprises  ten  independent  states  and 
a  number  of  small  sheikhdoms  and  protectorates.  With  an  area  of  2.1 
million  square  miles  it  is  greater  in  size  than  Europe,  excluding  the 
U.S.S.R.,  and  approximately  two-thirds  the  size  of  the  United  States.  The 
total  population,  however,  is  less  than  70  million  and  average  population 
density  is  only  32  persons  per  square  mile.  The  latter  figure  is  not  very 
meaningful,  however,  since  much  of  the  region  is  unfit  for  human  habita- 
tion or  is  unpeopled  except  for  nomads.  A  few  countries  like  Israel  and 
Lebanon  are  fairly  densely  populated  ( see  Table  20-1 ) . 

Southwest  Asia  is  an  area  of  high  birth  rates  and  declining  though  still 
high  death  rates.  During  the  period  of  1940  to  1950  average  population 
growth  in  Southwest  Asia  was  1.35  per  cent  per  year.  Population  growth 
rates  are  accelerating  and  according  to  United  Nations'  estimates  may 
reach  1.83  to  2.32  per  cent  per  year  by  1980.  This  would  give  Southwest 
Asia  a  population  of  99  to  106  million  by  that  time. 

TABLE  20-1 
Southwest  Asia:  Area,  Population,  and  Population  Density,  1953 


COUNTRY 


AREA 
(  SQUARE  MILES  ) 


POPULATION 

( THOUSANDS ) 


POPULATION  DENSITY 

(per  SQUARE  mile) 


Aden  Colony 

80 

150 

1,875 

Aden  Protectorate 

122,000 

650 

5.3 

Bahrein 

231 

112 

484 

Iran 

629,344 

20,253 

32 

Iraq 

168,114 

4,882  (1952) 

29 

Israel 

8,108 

1,650 

198 

Jordan 

37,264 

1,360 

36 

Kuwait 

8,000 

150 

19 

Lebanon 

4,016 

1,353 

337 

Muscat  and  Oman 

82,007 

550 

6.7 

Qatar 

8,500 

20 

2.3 

Saudi  Arabia 

617,700 

7,000  (1952) 

11.3 

Syria 

70,014 

3,535 

50.4 

Trucial  Oman 

5,792 

80 

13.8 

Turkey 

296.185 

22,461 

75.8 

Yemen 

75,290 

4,500  (1952) 

59.8 

Total 

2,132,645 

68,706 

32.2 

a  United  Nations,  Statistical  Yearbook,   1953. 

b  United    Nations,    Population    and    Vital    Statistics    Reports,    Series    A,    Vol.    7,    No.     1     (New    York, 
January,  19SS). 


626       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

GEOGRAPHY  AND  CLIMATE 

Southwest  Asia  divides  into  two  fairly  distinct  physical  areas.  In  the 
north  and  northeast  are  the  high  plateaus  of  Anatolia  and  Iran,  enclosed 
by  rugged  mountain  ranges,  and  having  average  elevations  of  4,000  feet. 
Narrow  coastal  belts  fringe  these  plateaus  along  the  Caspian  and  Black 
Seas  in  the  north  and  along  the  Aegean  and  Mediterranean  Seas  in  the 
west  and  southwest.  The  remainder  and  largest  part  of  Southwest  Asia 
(approximately  two-thirds)  forms  a  vast  level  plain  which  gradually 
slopes  upward  to  form  the  highlands  of  Saudi  Arabia  overlooking  the  Red 
Sea  and  the  Gulf  of  Aden. 

Although  Southwest  Asia  is  located  largely  in  tropical  latitudes,  it 
shows  wide  variations  in  climate.  The  coastal  regions  of  the  Mediterra- 
nean are  hot  in  summer  and  wet  and  cool  in  the  winter.  The  Anatolian 
and  Iranian  plateaus  are  generally  characterized  by  cold  winters  and  hot 
dry  summers.  Their  fringing  littoral  regions  are  wet  and  warm.  Arabia, 
except  for  the  southwest  which  has  a  monsoon  climate,  has  cold  winters 
and  little  or  no  rainfall. 

The  one  outstanding  climatic  characteristic  of  Southwest  Asia  is  its 
aridity.  Almost  all  of  Arabia,  much  of  Iraq,  and  most  of  eastern  and  cen- 
tral Iran  are  desert.  Rains  exceeding  24  inches  annually  are  largely  con- 
fined to  the  areas  bordering  the  Black  and  Caspian  Seas  in  the  north  and 
the  Aegean  and  Mediterranean  Seas  in  the  west  and  southwest.  Most  of 
the  region  has  less  than  8  inches  of  rain  and  over  half  has  less  than  4 
inches.  The  significance  of  this  lack  of  moisture  for  raising  food,  which  is 
the  principal  economic  activity  of  the  region,  is  apparent  in  view  of  the 
fact  that  wheat  will  not  grow  without  irrigation  where  rainfall  is  less  than 
8  inches. 

The  aridity  of  Southwest  Asia  has  had  a  major  influence  on  economic 
activity  in  the  area  and  on  the  distribution  of  population.  Population 
density  is  closely  correlated  with  rainfall.  As  a  result,  the  region  is  char- 
acterized by  numerous,  relatively  small,  cultivated  pockets  separated  by 
extensive  desert  area.  Although  large  areas  of  Southwest  Asia  lack  suffi- 
cient moisture  for  growing  crops,  they  do  support  vegetation  for  pastur- 
age. Thus  a  considerable  portion  of  the  total  population,  possibly  one- 
seventh,  is  nomadic  and  is  engaged  in  the  raising  of  livestock. 

RESOURCES 

In  terms  of  its  area,  Southwest  Asia  is  relatively  poor  both  in  good 
agricultural  land  and  in  mineral  resources  with  the  notable  exception  of 


SOUTHWEST  ASIA  627 

oil  (Fig.  20-1).  Most  of  the  region  is  mountain,  desert,  or  swamp.  The 
Food  and  Agricultural  Organization  of  the  United  Nations  classified 
roughly  8  per  cent  of  the  land  area  as  arable  as  compared  with  more  than 
23  per  cent  in  the  United  States.  This  is  not  to  say  that  the  area  lacks 
potentialities  for  further  economic  development.  Despite  a  somewhat  lim- 
ited resource  base,  much  of  Southwest  Asia  is  underpopulated  and  can 
support  a  considerably  larger  number  of  people  at  higher  levels  of  living, 
provided  these  resources  are  more  effectively  exploited.  Best  situated  re- 
source-wise are  Syria,  Iran,  Iraq,  and  Turkey.  Some  countries,  like  Israel, 
Lebanon,  and  Jordan,  have  serious  population  problems.  Large  oil  reserves 
offer  "at  least  six  countries  the  first  chance  for  centuries  to  break  out  of  the 
rut  of  poverty,  and  to  organize  a  rise  in  standards  of  living  and  education 
that  will  be  sudden  and  decisive  enough  to  outstrip  the  lusty  local  tend- 
ency to  a  high  birth  rate."  J  Nonetheless  even  in  the  most  promising  areas 
economic  growth  in  Southwest  Asia  may  continue  to  be  slow.  Technical 
skills  will  have  to  be  acquired.  The  proportion  of  total  production  devoted 
to  investment  will  have  to  be  greatly  increased.  And  most  important  in  a 
number  of  countries  major  institutional  and  social  changes  will  have  to 
come  about  to  establish  the  necessary  preconditions  for  sustained  eco- 
nomic growth. 

Agricultural  Land.  Compared  with  the  rest  of  the  continent,  Southwest 
Asia's  resources  of  arable  and  potentially  productive  land  area  in  relation 
to  the  population  are  relatively  favorable.  As  shown  in  Table  20-2,  arable 
land  amounts  to  roughly  1.7  acres  per  capita  and  ranges  from  less  than 
half  an  acre  in  Lebanon  to  approximately  2  acres  in  Syria,  Iran,  and  Tur- 
key. By  comparison,  cultivated  land  in  industrial  United  States  is  more 
than  2.5  acres  per  person,  whereas  in  primarily  agricultural  economies 
like  Australia,  New  Zealand,  or  Uruguay  and  Chile  it  is  more  than  4  acres 
per  capita.  Because  of  poor  methods  of  cultivation,  a  sizable  portion  of 
the  arable  land  lies  fallow  every  year  to  restore  its  fertility.  In  Iraq,  large 
tracts  of  arable  land  have  become  saline  because  of  poor  drainage,  result- 
ing in  a  serious  drop  in  yields. 

Estimates  of  potentially  productive  land  suggest  that  the  area  under 
cultivation  can  be  more  than  doubled  or  that  Southwest  Asia  could  grow 
enough  foodstuffs  to  feed  twice  its  present  population  at  existing  diet 
levels,  assuming  no  changes  in  farm  methods.  However,  the  estimate  of 
potentially  productive  land  must  be  considered  more  as  a  theoretical 
maximum  rather  than  as  a  figure  likely  soon  to  be  achieved.  Only  a  few 
countries— Syria,  Iraq,  and  Turkey— offer  some  possibilities  for  increased 

1  The  Economist,  July  2,  1955,  p.  16. 


3  A 


> 

lU 

628 


SOUTHWEST  ASIA 


629 


dry  farming.  Most  of  the  potentially  productive  land,  although  inherently 
fertile,  would  require  expensive  irrigation  and  drainage  projects  and  ex- 
tensive transportation  development.  Iran,  Iraq,  and  Syria  are  fortunate 
in  having  large  rivers  which  can  be  harnessed  to  supply  water.  Thus  the 
International  Bank  for  Reconstruction  and  Development  in  its  economic 
survey  of  Iraq  concluded  that  much  of  the  soil  is  inherently  fertile  and 
"with  ample  water,  manpower,  and  implements,  the  area  under  cultiva- 
tion might  be  almost  tripled."  -  Again,  the  Joint  United  States-Syria  Agri- 
cultural Mission  in  its  1946  survey  concluded  that  a  series  of  irrigation 
projects  drawing  on  the  Euphrates  and  its  tributaries  might  permit  an 
additional  2  million  acres  to  be  put  under  intensive  cultivation.  If  this 
were  done  these  areas  could  not  only  feed  their  growing  populations  but 
also  produce  considerable  food  for  export.  One  of  the  main  problems  is 
to  mobilize  the  required  capital.  An  additional  difficulty  is  that  some 
water-development  schemes,  such  as  the  proposed  Jordan  Valley  project, 
cut  across  national  boundaries  and  require  the  co-operation  of  nations 
highly  distrustful  of  each  others'  intentions— in  this  case,  the  Arab  states 
on  one  hand  and  Israel  on  the  other. 

TABLE  20-2 
Arable  and  Potentially  Productive  Land  * 


COUNTRY 

PERIOD 

ARABLE  LAND 

( THOUSANDS 

OF  ACRES) 

ARABLE  LAND 
PER  CAPITA 
( IN  ACRES ) 

POTENTIALLY 

PRODUCTIVE 

(  THOUSANDS 

OF  ACRES) 

Aden  Protectorate 

1947 

272 

0.4 

Iran 

1950 

41,414 

2.0 

81,543 

Iraq 

1951 

5,777 

1.2 

29,900 

Jordan 

1947 

1,186 

0.9 

Lebanon 

1950 

692 

0.5 

Israel 

1951 

981 ' 

0.6 

Syria 

1950 

8,737 

2.5 

9,578 

Turkey 

Total 

1949 

37,707 
96,766 

1.7 
1.7 

121,021 

a  Total  agricultural  area  including  permanent  meadows  and  pastures. 

*  United  Nations,    Food   and   Agriculture   Organization,    Yearbook    of   Food   and   Agricultural   Statistics, 
1952,  Vol.  6,  Part  1. 


Oil.  Oil  is  one  resource  Southwest  Asia  possesses  in  great  abundance 
(cf.  Fig.  20-1,  p.  628).  Indeed  the  location  of  the  world's  richest  oil  re- 
serves in  Southwest  Asia  accounts  in  large  part  for  the  great  interest  of  the 
major  world  powers  in  this  region.  In  1953  Southwest  Asia's  proven  re- 

2  The  Economic  Development  of  Iraq  (Baltimore,  1952),  p.  1. 


630        THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

serves  of  crude  petroleum  of  8.3  billion  metric  tons  amounted  to  roughly 
53  per  cent  of  the  world  total,  or  63  per  cent  if  the  Soviet  bloc  is  excluded. 
These  reserves  were  two  and  a  quarter  times  larger  than  those  of  the 
United  States.  Moreover,  these  reserves  yield  very  low-cost  oil.  It  costs  the 
Anglo-Iranian  Oil  Company  less  than  15  cents  to  produce  a  barrel  of  crude 
oil  as  compared  with  70  cents  in  Venezuela  and  $1.70  in  the  United  States.3 
As  shown  in  Table  20-3  a  few  countries,  principally  Iran,  Iraq,  Kuwait, 
and  Saudi  Arabia,  account  for  the  bulk  of  these  reserves. 

TABLE  20-3 

Southwest  Asia:   Estimated  Proven  Reserves  of  Crude  Petroleum 

by  Country  in   1953  * 
(in  millions  of  metric  tons) 

PER  CENT  OF 
COUNTRY  QUANTITY 

WORLD  TOTAL 

Bahrein 

Iran 

Iraq 

Kuwait 

Qatar 

Saudi  Arabia 

Turkey 


40.9 

neg. 

1,722.3 

11.05 

1,470.6 

9.44 

2,444.3 

15.69 

163.2 

1.05 

2,426.51 

15.57 

11.1 

neg. 

Total  Southwest  Asia  8,278.9  52.80 

United  States  3,809.6  24.45 

Venezuela  1,380.5  8.86 


World  Total  15,580.4  100.0 

*  World  Oil,  August  IS,   1954. 

The  magnitude  of  these  reserves  is  suggested  by  the  fact  that  they 
would  meet  total  United  States'  requirements  at  present  rates  of  consump- 
tion for  a  period  of  more  than  thirty  years.  Moreover,  these  proven  re- 
serves by  no  means  represent  the  total  oil  resources  of  the  region.  While 
these  reserves  have  been  expanding  rapidly  as  a  result  of  continued  ex- 
ploitation and  drilling  activities,  much  of  the  potential  oil-bearing  land 
of  the  region  is  still  untapped.  Thus  estimated  petroleum  reserves  in- 
creased by  more  than  25  per  cent  between  1951  and  1953.  A  more  recent 
estimate  made  for  the  U.S.  Joint  Congressional  Committee  on  Atomic 
Energy  placed  Southwest  Asia's  crude  oil  reserves  in  1956  at  230  billion 
barrels  or  more  than  double  the  previous  accepted  estimate. 3a  It  is  ex- 

3  The  Annals,  Vol.  294  (July,  1954),  p.  152. 

3a  Background  Material  for  the  Report  of  the  Panel  on  the  Impact  of  the  Peaceful 
Uses  of  Atomic  Energy  (Washington,  D.  C,  1956),  p.  92. 


SOUTHWEST  ASIA 


631 


pected  that  Southwest  Asia's  reserves  will  continue  to  increase  in  absolute 
terms  and  will  become  relatively  more  important  as  reserves  in  other  areas, 
particularly  the  United  States,  are  used  up.  By  1956,  Southwest  Asia's 
share  of  the  Free  World's  oil  reserves  had  increased  to  75  per  cent 

Other  Mineral  Resources.  Our  knowledge  of  Southwest  Asia's  other 
mineral  resources  suffers  from  the  fact  that  much  of  the  region  has  never 
been  adequately  surveyed.  Except  for  petroleum,  however,  the  area  ap- 
pears to  be  poor  in  mineral  resources.  Turkey,  the  only  country  in  the 
region  with  the  coal  and  iron  ore  required  to  support  heavy  industry,  is 
the  one  exception.  The  region's  deficiency  in  minerals  is  suggested  by  the 
low  output  figures  given  in  Table  20-4. 

TABLE  20-4 

Output  of  Minerals,  1939,  1943,  1945,  1948  to  1952  * 
(thousands  of  metric  tons) 


COUNTRY  AND  MINERAL 

1939 

1943 

1945 

1948 

1949 

1950 

1951 

1952 

Iran: 

Iron  oxide 

10 

0.2 

5 

11 

7 

Iraq: 

Salt 

11 

23 

15 

14 

Israel/Palestine: 

Potash  (K20  content) 

32 

47 

45 

50 

Salt 

9 

18 

20 

5 

9 

7 

2 

Lebanon: 

Salt 

7 

7 

8 

9 

Saudi  Arabia: 

Gold  (kilograms) 

4.97 

1326 

1181 

2300 

2079 

2059 

Syria: 

Salt 

14 

12 

15 

8 

21 

22 

Turkey: 

Antimony  (content) 

0.7 

— 

— 

0.5 

0.5 

1.3 

2.2 

Boracite 

15.2 

— 

5.0 

5.3 

7.1 

9.8 

Copper  (smelter 

production 

6.7 

9.7 

9.9 

11.0 

11.3 

11.7 

17.5 

19.1 

Chrome  ore  (Cr203 

content 

92 

76 

72 

140 

217 

202 

287 

Emery 

10 

7.8 

2.2 

7.9 

8.9 

1.2 

Iron  ore  (Fa  content) 

155 

59 

82 

121 

136 

143 

143 

195 

Manganese  ore  (Mn 

content) 

0.9 

1.1 

2.0 

3.3 

11.1 

15.8 

24.7 

Coal 

2696 

3166 

3720 

4023 

4183 

4360 

4730 

4863 

Lignite 

185 

625 

725 

1010 

1272 

1203 

1255 

1374 

Quicksilver 

13.6 

6.4 

5.4 

0.9 

— 

— 

Salt 

240 

266 

254 

266 

318 

310 

273 

Sulphur 

2.6 

3.4 

4.6 

2.6 

3.1 

6.0 

7.4 

*  United  Nations,  Department  of  Economic  Affairs,  Review  of  Economic  Conditions  in  the  Middle  East 
1951-1952  (March,  1953),  p.  122. 


632       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

Turkish  reserves  of  500  million  metric  tons  of  bituminous  coal  and  over 
125  million  tons  of  sub-bituminous  coal  are  ample  to  cover  the  country's 
foreseeable  needs.  Most  of  these  reserves  are  of  coking  quality  as  required 
for  steel-making.  Iron  ore  reserves,  however,  are  relatively  small,  amount- 
ing to  15  to  35  million  metric  tons  with  an  iron  content  of  65  per  cent. 
Lower-grade  ore  also  has  been  found.  Turkey  has  large  reserves  of  high- 
grade  chromium  and  is  now  a  major  world  supplier.  Turkey's  copper 
reserves  are  estimated  at  from  4  to  8  million  tons.  A  large  number  of  small 
manganese  deposits  are  also  found  in  Turkey. 

Although  a  variety  of  minerals  have  been  found  in  other  parts  of 
Southwest  Asia  besides  Turkey,  they  generally  have  been  low  in  quality 
and  limited  in  amount  or  located  in  inaccessible  areas.  In  many  instances 
not  enough  information  is  available  about  these  deposits  to  tell  whether 
they  will  warrant  commercial  exploitation. 

EXTENT  AND  CHARACTER  OF  ECONOMIC  DEVELOPMENT 

Southwest  Asia  is  in  no  sense  an  economic  unity.  Quite  the  contrary. 
Economic  ties  between  the  countries  of  Southwest  Asia  are  minor.  The 
chief  reason  for  this  is  that  their  economies  are  essentially  competing 
rather  than  complementary.  The  limited  economic  relationships  between 
the  countries  of  Southwest  Asia  is  indicated  by  the  fact  that  intra-regional 
trade  is  only  about  5  per  cent  of  total  trade.  This  compares  with  30  per 
cent  for  the  rest  of  Asia  and  more  than  50  per  cent  for  Western  Europe. 

All  of  the  countries  of  Southwest  Asia  except  possibly 'Israel  are  under- 
developed. Average  annual  per  capita  income  of  the  region  in  1949  was 
only  about  $125.  Only  a  few  countries,  notably  Turkey,  Lebanon,  and 
Israel,  have  per  capita  incomes  appreciably  higher  than  the  average.  Low 
incomes  are  reflected  in  diets  for  most  of  the  area,  which  are  inadequate 
from  a  nutritional  point  of  view  and  malnutrition  is  quite  widespread. 
During  the  period  1946  to  1949  the  calorie  content  of  food  supplies  avail- 
able for  human  consumption  in  Iran  and  Iraq  was  less  than  2000  per 
person  per  day.4 

Agriculture  is  the  principal  economic  activity  and  supports  the  bulk  of 
the  population.  For  most  countries  75  per  cent  or  more  of  the  employed 
population  works  in  agriculture  and  animal  husbandry.  Except  for  Turkey 
the  area  has  no  heavy  industry.  Manufactures  are  confined  largely  to  the 
production  of  consumer  goods  and  the  processing  of  foodstuffs. 

4  United  Nations,  Food  and  Agriculture  Organization,  Current  Developments  of 
and  Prospects  for  Agriculture  in  the  Near  East,  1951. 


SOUTHWEST  ASIA  633 

Production  per  worker  in  agriculture  and  in  industry  by  Western 
standards  is  low.  During  the  five-year  period  1947  to  1951  productivity  in 
agriculture  was  only  62  per  cent  of  the  world  average  and  roughly  20  per 
cent  of  that  of  North  America.  Productivity  in  industry  as  compared  with 
developed  countries  is  even  less  favorable  than  in  agriculture. 

Fuel  and  power  consumption,  which  is  one  of  the  best  measures  of 
economic  development,  was  less  than  0.50  metric  tons  (coal  equivalent) 
per  person  in  1949.  This  compares  with  7.32  metric  tons  for  the  United 
States  and  more  than  two  and  a  half  metric  tons  for  most  Western  Euro- 
pean countries. 

Literacy  levels  with  few  exceptions  are  very  low.  In  most  countries 
less  than  10  per  cent  of  the  population  over  ten  years  of  age  can  read. 

Southwest  Asia's  exports  consist  largely  of  food  and  raw  materials  and 
its  imports  of  manufactures.  For  most  countries  two  or  three  commodities 
frequently  account  for  a  high  percentage  of  the  value  of  all  merchandise 
exports.  As  a  result  their  economies  are  highly  vulnerable  to  foreign  mar- 
ket forces  over  which  they  have  little  or  no  control.  Merchandise  imports 
are  greatly  in  excess  of  exports.  The  deficit  is  financed  largely  from  earn- 
ings on  oil  sales,  foreign  grants  and  loans,  and  donations  and  remittances. 

While  a  few  countries  like  Turkey  and  Israel  have  enjoyed  moderate 
economic  progress  in  recent  years,  the  area  by  and  large  suffers  from 
economic  stagnation.  Savings  and  investment  are  low  and  are  just  about 
adequate  to  meet  the  needs  of  the  rising  population.  Much  of  the  income 
of  wealthy  potential  savers  goes  into  luxurious  living.  As  a  result  living 
standards  have  shown  little  or  no  improvement  in  the  past  decade  or 
more.  While  many  countries  in  the  region  have  embarked  on  programs  to 
speed  up  their  economic  development,  progress  to  date  has  been  slow. 
Except  in  the  case  of  the  oil-producing  countries  lack  of  capital  has  been 
a  major  obstacle.  The  rich  oil-producing  countries  have  been  plagued  by 
many  other  problems  such  as  inefficient  governments,  political  instability, 
and  the  resistance  of  the  ruling  classes  to  major  social  and  economic 
changes. 

AGRICULTURE 

Most  of  the  agricultural  land  of  Southwest  Asia  is  devoted  to  the  pro- 
duction of  wheat,  barley,  maize,  and  rice  for  domestic  consumption. 
Except  for  a  few  years  following  World  War  II  the  area  traditionally  has 
had  a  cereal  surplus,  with  the  large  exports  of  Turkey,  Syria,  and  Iraq 
exceeding  the  deficits  of  the  rest  of  the  region.  Cash  crops  such  as  citrus 
fruits,  cotton,  sugar,  oil-seeds,  tobacco,  dates,  and  olive  oil  have  been  of 


634       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

increasing  importance  with  the  development  of  transportation  and  the 
growth  of  export  markets.  Some  areas,  particularly  on  the  Arabian  Penin- 
sula, because  of  the  poverty  of  the  soil  will  support  only  pastoral  nomad- 
ism. But  the  numbers  of  people  involved  are  comparatively  few. 

Cultivation  is  typically  small-scale,  the  average  family  working  a  plot 
of  five  to  seven  acres.  Methods  of  cultivation  are  extremely  primitive  and 
largely  account  for  low  yields  per  worker  of  one-eighth  to  one-quarter 
those  in  Western  Europe  or  the  United  States.  Despite  the  lack  of  water, 
modern  irrigation  methods  have  been  introduced  only  on  a  limited  scale 
except  in  Iraq,  Iran,  and  Israel.  Farm  implements  are  chiefly  hand  tools 
and  animal-drawn  equipment.  Very  little  power  equipment  is  employed 
except  on  the  larger  estates.  In  1952,  it  was  estimated  that  the  number 
of  tractors  in  use  in  Iran,  Iraq,  Lebanon,  Syria,  and  Turkey  totalled  less 
than  37,000.  Almost  90  per  cent  of  these  were  in  Turkey.5  Fertilizer  con- 
sumption is  negligible  in  most  countries  and  is  not  even  sufficient  to  re- 
place a  small  fraction  of  the  nutrients  extracted  from  the  soil  through 
cultivation.6  Only  a  few  countries  use  high-yield  seed  varieties  and  every 
year  crop  yields  are  substantially  reduced  as  a  result  of  pests  and  disease. 
For  example,  it  is  estimated  that  15  per  cent  of  Iran's  total  agricultural 
production  is  lost  through  insects,  rodents,  waste,  and  spoilage.7 

A  number  of  irrigation  and  multipurpose  projects  of  the  TVA  variety 
have  been  planned  or  proposed  to  improve  agricultural  conditions  in 
Southwest  Asia.  Among  these  is  the  previously  mentioned  Jordan  Valley 
Development  scheme,  which  is  strongly  supported  by  the  United  States 
Government  because  of  the  contribution  it  will  make  toward  relieving  the 
Arab  refugee  problem.  The  plan  as  prepared  under  the  direction  of  the 
United  Nations  would  irrigate  234,000  acres  of  land  in  Israel,  Jordan,  and 
Syria,  much  of  which  could  then  produce  crops  the  year  round.  In  addi- 
tion, the  scheme  would  produce  65,000  kilowatts  of  electric  power.  Iraq 
has  vast  flood  control  and  irrigation  works  already  under  way  which  when 
completed  will  nearly  double  the  present  area  of  irrigated  land. 

The  extensive  discussions  held  between  the  countries  interested  in  the 
Jordan  Valley  project  illustrate  the  difficulties  of  obtaining  agreement  on 
river  schemes  involving  international  rivers.  In  this  case  four  countries 
lay  claim  to  the  waters  of  the  Jordan.  Even  in  the  most  favorable  political 
atmosphere,  reaching  agreement  on  such  questions  as  to  how  the  avail- 
able waters  are  to  be  divided,  sharing  of  costs,  and  where  the  dams  and 

5  United  Nations,  Food  and  Agriculture  Organization,  Agriculture  in  the  Near  East 
(November,  1953),  p.  52. 
«  Ibid.,  p.  57. 
7  Department  of  State,  Agriculture  In  Point  4  Countries,  Part  4  (August,  1952). 


SOUTHWEST  ASIA  635 

power  installations  should  be  located  is  difficult.  In  the  case  of  the  Jordan 
Valley  Development  project  these  difficulties  have  been  greatly  magnified 
by  the  bitterness  of  Israeli-Arab  relations.  To  minimize  or  eliminate  the 
need  for  direct  Arab-Israeli  negotiations,  it  has  been  proposed  that  the 
project  be  placed  under  international  administration  and  supervision. 
Whether  or  not  arrangements  can  be  worked  out  so  that  the  project  can 
go  forward  is  still  uncertain. 

Extreme  inequalities  in  the  ownership  of  land  are  an  important  cause 
of  rural  poverty  and  a  major  source  of  political  and  social  unrest  in  many 
parts  of  Southwest  Asia.  Except  in  Israel,  in  Jordan,  and  in  parts  of  Leba- 
non and  Turkey,  the  principal  form  of  tenure  is  that  of  large  estates 
cultivated  by  tenants,  many  of  whom  are  share-croppers.  Thus  in  Iran 
an  estimated  90  per  cent  of  the  rural  population  are  tenant  share-crop- 
pers.8 A  few  absentee  landlords  (including  the  Shah),  religious  endow- 
ments, and  the  government  own  most  of  the  land.  Large  holdings  of  tribal 
sheikhs  and  other  wealthy  individuals  are  also  the  general  rule  in  Iraq. 
According  to  a  recent  United  Nations  study,  "landlords  supply  little 
capital  to  agriculture  and  exact  excessive  rents  from  tenants,  who  enjoy 
little  security.  In  spite  of  some  improvement  in  recent  years,  agricultural 
credit  facilities  are  inadequate,  and  the  peasants  pay  high  rates  of  interest 
to  money-lenders.  Many  measures  of  reform  are  needed,  security  of  tenure 
and  wider  opportunities  of  ownership  and  further  development  of  the 
co-operative  movement,  among  others."  9  Only  Turkey,  with  its  land- 
reform  policy  initiated  in  1945,  has  taken  effective  action  to  develop 
peasant  proprietorship.  In  Israel,  farming  settlement  is  primarily  com- 
munal or  co-operative. 

INDUSTRY 

Except  for  petroleum,  industry  is  relatively  unimportant  in  Southwest 
Asia  in  terms  of  the  numbers  employed  and  the  contribution  to  national 
output.  Only  Turkey  and  Israel  have  made  significant  strides  in  the  direc- 
tion of  greater  industrialization.  And  only  in  Israel  is  the  contribution  of 
industry  to  national  income  greater  than  that  of  agriculture.  Light  indus- 
tries producing  textiles  and  possessing  foodstuffs  for  domestic  consump- 
tion predominate.  Handicrafts  still  account  for  a  large  proportion  of  the 
area's  output  of  manufactures.  Turkey  with  its  modest  iron  and  steel  in- 
dustry is  the  only  country  in  the  region  with  any  heavy  industry. 

Turkey's  industrialization  has  occurred  largely  at  government  initiative 

8  Ibid.,  p.  12. 

9  United  Nations,  Progress  In  Land  Reform  (New  York,  1954). 


636       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

and  was  largely  motivated  by  the  desire  to  strengthen  the  power  of  the 
state.  Government  banks  own  and  operate  about  three-fourths  of  Turkey's 
industry.  Despite  its  comparative  progress  Turkey  is  still  a  long  way  from 
being  an  industrialized  state.  Only  8  per  cent  of  the  labor  force  are  in 
industry  as  against  64  per  cent  in  agriculture.  Turkey's  crude  steel  output 
of  roughly  150,000  tons  per  annum  is  only  one-third  that  of  Yugoslavia. 

Israel's  industrialization,  in  contrast  with  that  of  Turkey,  has  been 
brought  about  largely  through  the  initiative  of  private  entrepreneurs. 
Light  metals  and  machinery  and  food  processing  are  of  greatest  impor- 
tance. 

As  in  agriculture,  productivity  in  industry  is  very  low  by  Western 
standards.  The  reasons  are  largely  the  same  as  in  agriculture.  They  in- 
clude insufficient  and  inadequate  industrial  equipment,  lack  of  competent 
supervisory  personnel  and  poorly  trained  workers,  inadequate  supplies 
of  locally  produced  raw  materials,  and  so  on. 

PETROLEUM  INDUSTRY 

The  petroleum  industry  is  by  far  the  region's  most  important  industry. 
Production  of  petroleum  has  expanded  rapidly  in  Southwest  Asia  since 
the  war,  largely  in  response  to  the  great  increase  in  world  consumption. 
In  1953  the  area  produced  121.7  million  metric  tons  of  crude  oil  or 
roughly  18  per  cent  of  the  world  total— or  20  per  cent  if  we  exclude  the 
Soviet  bloc.  Table  20-5  shows  the  region's  crude  oil  output  by  countries 
for  the  years  1948  and  1950  through  1953. 

TABLE  20-5 

Southwest  Asia:   Crude  Production  by  Country,  1948  and  1950-53  * 
(thousands  of  metric  tons) 


COUNTRY 

1948 

1950 

1951 

1952 

1953 

Bahrein 

1,496 

1,511 

1,508 

1,510 

1,506 

Iran 

25,270 

32,259 

16,844 

1,348 

1,366 

Iraq 

3,427 

6,479 

8,690 

18,850 

28,200 

Kuwait 

6,400 

17,291 

28,327 

37,631 

42,654 

Quatar 

— 

1,636 

2,370 

3,296 

4,003 

Saudi  Arabia 

19,260 

26,301 

37,476 

40,698 

41,566 

Turkey 

3 

17 

19 

22 

28 

Total  Southwest  Asia 

57,742 

88,613 

97,566 

105,707 

121,673 

World  Total 

470,000 

525,000 

592,000 

623,000 

666,000 

Southwest  Asia's  Share 

of  World  Total 

12.3 

16.9 

16.5 

17.0 

18.4 

*  United   Nations,   Department   of   Economic   Affairs,   Summary    of   Recent   Economic   Development    in 
the  Middle  East  1952-53  (New  York,  1954),  p.  17. 


SOUTHWEST  ASIA  637 

The  sharp  drop  in  Iranian  output  during  and  after  1951  reflects  the 
virtual  stoppage  of  oil  operations  during  the  dispute  between  Anglo- 
Iranian  Oil  and  the  Iranian  Government  over  nationalization  of  the  in- 
dustry. It  is  estimated  that  in  1953  crude  productive  capacity  in  Iran  and 
elsewhere  in  the  region  was  at  least  50  million  tons,  or  roughly  40  per  cent 
more  than  actual  production.10 

Refinery  Capacity.  Most  of  the  oil  produced  in  Southwest  Asia  is 
shipped  out  of  the  region  as  crude  oil.  In  1950,  before  the  shutting  down 
of  the  Abadan  refinery  in  Iran,  which  is  the  largest  in  the  world  ( cf.  Fig. 
20-1,  p.  628).  Southwest  Asia's  output  of  refinery  products  aggregated 
about  40  million  tons  or  9  per  cent  of  the  world  total.  In  1952  refinery  out- 
put was  down  to  23.6  million  tons  or  to  slightly  less  than  4  per  cent  of  the 
world  total.  In  1952  the  annual  crude  charging  capacity  of  the  refineries 
of  the  region  exceeded  50  million  tons  and  was  gradually  being  expanded. 
Output  of  major  refineries  products  by  countries  for  the  period  1950-52  is 
given  in  Table  20-6. 

TABLE  20-6 

Southwest  Asia:   Output  of  Major  Refinery  Products  by  Countries,   1950-52  * 

(thousands  of  metric  tons) 


COUNTRY 

1950 

1951 

1952 

Bahrein 

6,841 

8,040 

8,621 

Iran 

24,665 

12,807 a 

1,332 a 

Israel 

187 

707 

805  b 

Kuwait 

1,101 

1,203 

1,326 

Lebanon 

394 

420 

461 

Saudi  Arabia 

4,825 

7,395 

7,971 

Turkey 

5 
40,521 

6 

5 

Total 

33,224 

23,607 

a  Partly   estimated. 

b  Estimated. 

*  United   Nations,    op.   cit. 

Ownership  of  the  Petroleum  Industry.  Subsoil  rights  to  oil  in  Southwest 
Asia  are  almost  universally  vested  in  the  State.  However,  except  for  Iran, 
which  nationalized  the  properties  of  Anglo-Iranian  oil  in  1950,  exploita- 
tion of  Southwest  Asia's  oil  resources  is  predominantly  in  the  hands  of 
foreign  enterprises.  In  1953,  American  companies  controlled  about  60  per 
cent  of  the  area's  output,  British  and  British-Dutch  companies  35  per  cent, 
and  French  concerns  5  per  cent.  These  foreign  oil  concessionaires  operate 
under  profit-sharing  agreements  with  the  local  governments.  While  the 

10  Ibid.,  p.  46. 


638        THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

exact  details  of  these  agreements  vary  from  country  to  country,  they  uni- 
formly provide  for  an  equal  sharing  of  the  net  operating  revenues  of  the 
oil  company.  In  1954  the  Iranian  Government  turned  over  the  operation 
of  its  oil  industry  to  a  consortium  of  foreign  companies. 

Economic  Significance  of  Petroleum  to  Southwest  Asia.  The  Southwest 
Asian  oil  producing  countries  derive  very  significant  economic  benefits 
from  petroleum.  These  benefits  are  primarily  indirect  and  are  represented 
by  oil  company  royalties  and  other  payments  to  the  local  governments, 
local  expenditures  of  the  oil  companies  for  labor  and  supplies,  employ- 
ment, and  so  on.  It  is  estimated  that  in  1952  the  operations  of  the  oil 
companies  contributed  as  much  as  two-fifths  to  the  combined  national 
income  of  Saudi  Arabia,  Kuwait,  Iraq,  Qatar,  and  Bahrein.  Before  nation- 
alization 10  per  cent  of  Iran's  national  income  came  from  the  oil  industry. 
Although  petroleum  is  the  principal  source  of  energy  in  the  region,  only 
a  small  fraction  of  total  production  is  consumed  locally.  In  1952,  South- 
west Asia's  consumption  of  petroleum  amounted  roughly  to  6.5  million 
metric  tons,  or  about  5  per  cent  of  production.  Exports  including  bunker- 
ing fuel  exceeded  97  million  metric  tons  in  1952. 

The  largest  economic  benefits  derived  from  oil  are  represented  by  di- 
rect payments  of  oil  companies  to  the  local  governments.  These  payments 
consist  of  royalties,  taxes,  dead  rent  and  certain  other  items.  In  1953  they 
amounted  to  roughly  half  a  billion  dollars  and  in  1954  to  about  $700 
million. 

Local  employees  of  the  oil  companies  in  1951  numbered  more  than 
100,000.  Wage  payments  to  these  employees  plus  company  purchases  of 
local  materials  and  supplies  make  an  important  contribution  to  economic 
activity  in  the  areas  where  the  oil  companies  operate. 

As  a  result  of  their  large  incomes  from  oil  the  petroleum-producing 
territories  of  Southwest  Asia  have  been  afforded  an  important  means  of 
financing  much  needed  economic  development.  So  far,  however,  only  a 
few,  notably  Iraq  and  Kuwait,  have  taken  advantage  of  this  opportunity. 
A  good  part  of  the  income  is  still  being  dissipated  by  individual  rulers  on 
personal  expenditures. 

Importance  of  Southwest  Asia's  Oil  to  the  Free  World.  Southwest  Asia 
is  the  world's  most  important  exporter  of  petroleum.  The  bulk  of  its  ex- 
ports go  to  Eastern  Hemisphere  markets.  In  1953,  Free  World  countries 
outside  of  the  Americas  obtained  about  70  per  cent  of  their  petroleum 
requirements  from  Southwest  Asia,  while  the  proportion  for  Western 
Europe  exceeded  90  per  cent.  Although  American  companies  accounted 
for  the  largest  share  of  the  region's  output,  the  United  States  obtained 


SOUTHWEST  ASIA  639 

only  about  3  per  cent  of  its  requirements  from  this  source.  Thus  while 
American  oil  companies  have  a  significant  economic  stake  in  Southwest 
Asia's  oil  resources  in  terms  of  investment  and  revenues,  the  United  States 
economy  is  not  now  dependent  upon  oil  from  this  area.  For  Western 
European  countries,  by  contrast,  Southwest  Asia's  oil  is  of  vital  impor- 
tance. It  is  doubtful  whether  sufficient  oil  could  be  obtained  from  alter- 
native sources  to  meet  Western  Europe's  needs  except  possibly  over  a 
long  period  of  time  and  at  great  cost.  Moreover,  such  oil  as  could  be 
obtained  elsewhere  would  be  more  expensive,  would  have  to  be  paid  for 
largely  with  dollars,  and  would  impose  a  heavy  drain  on  Western  Eu- 
rope's balance-of-payments  position.  Finally,  Southwest  Asia's  oil  is  an 
important  source  of  earnings  particularly  for  the  British  and  the  Dutch. 

In  the  event  of  a  war,  Southwest  Asia's  oil  would  be  of  vital  importance 
to  the  Free  World.  Western  Hemisphere  supplies  alone  would  be  wholly 
inadequate  to  meet  the  essential  civilian  and  military  requirements  of  the 
United  States  and  its  Allies. 

In  the  years  ahead,  Southwest  Asia's  oil  is  likely  to  become  of  increas- 
ing economic  importance  to  the  United  States  as  consumption  continues 
to  rise  and  reserves  eventually  dwindle.  So  far,  despite  frequent  pessimis- 
tic predictions  that  United  States'  crude  oil  reserves  would  soon  be 
exhausted,  new  discoveries  have  outpaced  production.  However,  this  can- 
not keep  up  indefinitely.  In  fact,  during  the  past  five  years  United  States 
demand  for  crude  has  started  to  exceed  production.  If,  as  estimated  by 
the  Paley  Commission,  United  States  demand  for  petroleum  by  1975  is 
double  the  1950  amount,  dependence  on  foreign  supplies,  particularly 
from  Southwest  Asia,  will  be  much  greater  than  now.11 

COMMUNICATIONS 

Southwest  Asia,  which  is  a  land  bridge  connecting  three  continents,  is 
a  vital  link  in  the  world  communications  network.  Its  present  significance 
dates  in  considerable  measure  from  the  opening  of  the  Suez  Canal  in 
1869.  As  a  result  Southwest  Asia  has  become  a  cornerstone  of  the  highly 
important  Suez  Canal-Red  Sea-Strait  of  Bab-el- Mandeb  water  route 
which  enables  vessels  up  to  45,000  tons  to  pass  directly  from  the  Eastern 
Mediterranean  to  the  Red  Sea  and  Indian  Ocean. 

This  route  is  followed  by  virtually  all  shipping  from  Europe  to  the  Far 
East  and  Australia.  It  is  of  major  importance  to  all  maritime  powers,  and 

11  The  President's  Materials  Policy  Commission,  Resources  For  Freedom  ( Washing- 
ton, D.  C,  June,  1952),  p.  107. 


640       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

in  particular  to  the  United  Kingdom,  with  its  large  economic  interests  in 
South  Asia  and  the  Far  East.  The  economic  advantages  of  this  route  are 
demonstrated  by  the  fact  that  the  distance  from  London  to  Bombay  via 
the  Suez  Canal  is  4,500  miles  less  than  by  the  Cape  of  Good  Hope  route. 
The  resultant  savings  in  transportation  costs  contributed  significantly  to 
the  growth  of  trade  between  Europe  and  Asia,  The  Red  Sea-Suez  Canal 
water  route  has  assumed  increasing  significance  in  recent  years  with  the 
large  movements  of  petroleum  from  the  Persian  Gulf., 

The  Suez  Canal  greatly  outranks  in  importance  all  other  international 
canals  in  terms  of  volume  of  traffic  handled.  In  1952  over  86  million  net 
registered  tons  of  shipping  moved  through  the  Suez  Canal  as  compared 
with  34.5  million  tons  for  the  Panama  Canal  The  largest  share  of  this 
traffic  has  always  been  and  continues  to  be  British.  It  is  not  surprising 
that  the  British  had  grave  misgivings  about  relinquishing  its  control  over 
the  Canal  Zone  to  Egypt.  The  United  States  now  ranks  second  to  the 
United  Kingdom,  largely  because  of  oil  shipments  from  Saudi  Arabia. 

Andre  Siegfried  has  described  the  significance  of  the  Suez  Canal  as 
follows:  12 

Of  all  the  great  roadways  of  the  world,  the  sea  road  to  India  via  the  Isthmus 
of  Suez  is  probably  the  most  important,  for  it  joins  East  and  West  Asia  and 
Europe,— that  is,  the  two  most  thickly  populated  continents  having  the  most 
ancient  civilizations.  The  Isthmus  itself,  by  virtue  of  its  geographical  position, 
has  always  been  a  focal  point,  but  its  greatest  significance  dates  from  the  open- 
ing of  the  Canal,  in  1869,  at  a  time  when  Europe  was  triumphantly  expanding, 
thanks  to  the  industrial  revolution  and  steam  navigation.  The  rapid  pace  of 
industrialization  could  not  have  kept  pace  without  access  to  raw  materials  from 
the  outermost  parts  of  the  earth  and  the  opening  of  new  markets  for  manufac- 
tured goods.  And  the  introduction  of  America  to  the  Far  East  in  the  Twentieth 
century  further  enlarged  the  role  of  this  intercontinental  route.  If  the  Canal  is 
blocked  or  its  efficiency  impaired  the  whole  Western  World  is  affected. 

While  not  a  great  international  water  route  like  the  Suez  Canal,  the 
Straits  are  of  considerable  economic  and  strategic  importance  because 
they  provide  the  only  water  passage  between  the  Black  Sea  and  the 
Mediterranean.  Concern  over  control  of  the  Straits  has  always  been  im- 
portant to  the  U.S.S.R.  because  of  the  otherwise  landlocked  position  of 
Southern  Russia.  This  explains  why  Russia  has  consistently  sought  to 
obtain  the  right  to  uninterrupted  passage  through  the  Straits  in  peace  and 
war. 

Southwest  Asia's  oil  pipelines  are  also  of  great  international  economic 

12  "The  Suez:  International  Roadway,"  Foreign  Affairs,  Vol.  31,  No.  4  (July,  1953), 
pp.  604-618;  see  also  p.  241. 


SOUTHWEST  ASIA  641 

significance  13  (cf.  Fig.  20-1).  Most  important  are  the  two  large-diameter 
pipelines  from  Saudi  Arabia  and  Iraq  to  the  Mediterranean.  The  pipeline 
from  Saudi  Arabia,  completed  late  in  1950,  stretches  from  the  oilfields  of 
Saudi  Arabia,  through  Jordan  and  Syria,  to  Sidon  in  Lebanon.  This  thirty 
to  thirty-one-inch  pipeline,  with  a  length  of  1,720  kilometers  and  a  present 
throughput  capacity  of  15.5  million  tons  a  year,  required  an  investment 
of  $230  million.  The  Iraqi  pipeline,  with  diameters  of  twenty-six,  thirty, 
and  thirty-two  inches,  and  a  length  of  895  kilometers,  has  a  normal 
throughput  capacity  of  13.5  million  tons  a  year.  The  line  was  completed 
in  1952  from  Kirkuk  field  in  Iraq  to  Baniyas  in  Syria;  it  required  a  total 
investment  of  about  $115  million. 

In  addition  to  these  lines,  the  pipeline  systems  of  several  oil  producing 
countries  were  expanded  during  the  past  three  years.  In  Iraq,  a  pipeline 
of  twelve  to  sixteen  inches,  with  a  length  of  120  kilometers,  was  laid 
between  the  Zubair  field  and  Fao  on  the  Persian  Gulf;  it  has  a  crude 
carrying  capacity  of  2.6  million  tons  annually.  This  line  was  finished  late 
in  1951;  in  1952  plans  were  laid  to  construct  a  parallel  line  with  a  diameter 
of  twenty-four  inches.  There  was  another  plan,  also,  to  construct  a  pipe- 
line of  twelve  and  three-quarter  inches,  with  a  length  of  about  220  kilo- 
meters, capable  of  carrying  1.3  million  tons  of  crude  petroleum  a  year 
from  Ain  Zalah  to  the  main  Iraqi  pipelines  near  Shuraimiya.  The  con- 
struction of  a  sixteen-inch  pipeline  from  Kirkuk  to  Haifa,  which  was 
interrupted  in  1948,  was  not  completed.  Another  parallel  twelve-inch 
pipeline  from  Kirkuk  to  Haifa,  which  was  shut  down  in  1948,  remains 
closed.  In  Saudi  Arabia,  the  pipeline  system  was  expanded  in  1951  by  76 
kilometers  of  new  pipelines  with  a  capacity  of  nearly  14  million  tons  of 
crude  petroleum  a  year.  During  the  past  three  years  additional  pipelines 
were  laid  in  Iran,  Kuwait,  and  Qatar.  Expansion  of  oil  handling  facilities 
also  included  construction  of  storage  and  harbor  facilities  in  the  new  oil 
ports  of  Sidon,  Baniyas,  and  Fao,  as  well  as  expansion  of  existing  facilities 
in  Iran,  Kuwait,  Qatar,  and  Saudi  Arabia. 

The  rapid  growth  of  international  air  transport  also  has  contributed 
to  the  importance  of  Southwest  Asia  in  the  world  communications  net- 
work. Southwest  Asia  is  an  essential  transit  area  on  the  international  air 
routes  between  Europe  and  the  Far  East,  the  United  States  and  the  Far 
East,  and  Europe  and  Cape  Town.  At  the  present  time  a  large  number 
of  different  international  air  routes  cross  Arabia.  Air  transport  also  has 
contributed  significantly  to  the  improvement  of  local  communications. 

13  United  Nations,  Review  of  Economic  Conditions  in  the  Middle  East  1951-52, 
Ch.  3,  "Petroleum,"  pp.  53-66. 


642       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

The  principal  rail  systems  of  Southwest  Asia  (cf.  Fig.  20-1)  were  de- 
veloped by  foreign  powers  primarily  for  strategic  and  political  reasons 
and  have  only  limited  international  or  domestic  economic  significance.  In 
1951  the  quantity  of  freight  moved  per  capita  was  only  about  2  per  cent  of 
that  of  the  United  States.  There  are  two  main  systems.  One  extends  from 
Europe  via  Turkey  to  Egypt  and  the  Persian  Gulf.  The  other  starts  at  the 
Arabian  Gulf,  crosses  Iran  in  a  north  northeastern  direction  and  reaches 
the  Caspian  Sea  near  the  Soviet  border.  Both  systems  were  linked  during 
the  war  but  are  now  separated.  During  the  war  the  Trans-Iranian  railroad 
was  of  great  significance  in  moving  American  supplies  from  the  Persian 
Gulf  to  the  Soviet  Union.  The  railroad  from  Basra  to  Turkey  via  Baghdad 
also  was  important  during  World  War  II  for  the  movement  of  cargo  to 
Turkey,  since  the  Mediterranean  was  virtually  closed  to  Allied  shipping. 


CHAPTER 


21 


South  and  Southeast  Asia 


A  POWER  VACUUM 

South  and  Southeast  Asia  is  largely  a  power  vacuum  perilously  close 
to  the  Communist  bloc  and  a  primary  target  of  Communist  expansionist 
ambitions.  Before  World  War  II  the  entire  region  except  Thailand  and 
Afghanistan  was  under  direct  foreign  domination.  India,  Burma,  Malaya, 
Borneo,  and  Ceylon  were  controlled  by  the  United  Kingdom;  Indonesia 
by  the  Netherlands;  Indochina  by  France,  and  the  Philippines  by  the 
United  States.  After  World  War  II  most  of  the  area  became  independent 
but  none  of  the  newly  formed  states  have  as  yet  achieved  any  real  political 
and  economic  strength.  Some  of  the  governments  of  the  area  are  weak 
and  inexperienced;  a  number  of  countries  are  beset  by  serious  internal 
disorders.  Limited  progress  has  been  made  in  breaking  with  the  misery 
and  poverty  of  the  past.  As  a  result  discontent  and  frustration  are  prob- 
ably a  greater  threat  to  the  political  stability  of  South  and  Southeast  Asia 
than  of  any  other  underdeveloped  area.  At  the  same  time  Communist 
influence  has  greatly  increased  in  Asia  as  a  result  of  the  consolidation  of 
Chinese  Communist  power  on  the  mainland.  It  is  not  surprising  therefore 
that  Communists  have  been  making  a  major  effort  to  expand  their  influ- 
ence over  the  area  by  propaganda,  economic  blandishments,  infiltration, 
and  outright  conquest. 

Vital  interests  of  the  Free  World  are  threatened.  South  and  Southeast 
Asia  have  more  than  one-quarter  of  the  world's  total  population  and  al- 
most 40  per  cent  of  the  population  of  the  Free  World.  The  area  is  an 
important  source  of  raw  materials  as  well  as  a  market  for  exports.  It  occu- 

643 


644        THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

pies  a  highly  strategic  geographical  position  on  the  periphery  of  the  Asian 
land  mass.  It  dominates  important  air  and  sea  routes  and  controls  major 
air  and  naval  bases.  The  control  of  the  area  by  unfriendly  powers  would 
endanger  the  entire  Western  Pacific  defensive  system.  This  threat  to  its 
vital  security  interests  accounts  in  part  at  least  for  the  West's  large-scale 
economic  and  military  aid  to  the  region.  Thailand,  Pakistan,  and  the  Phil- 
ippines have  joined  the  West  as  parties  to  the  Manila  Pact  and  Pacific 
Charter  of  September,  1954,  to  protect  the  area  against  both  open  armed 
attack  and  internal  subversion.  Most  of  the  region,  however,  is  as  yet 
uncommitted  and  is  making  every  effort  to  remain  neutral.  Whether  such 
a  neutral  course  will  be  possible  remains  to  be  seen.  In  any  case  there 
appears  to  be  no  early  prospect  of  a  relaxation  of  Communist  efforts  to 
win  the  area. 

AREA  AND  POPULATION 

Despite  its  diversity  South  and  Southeast  Asia  has  an  essential  unity 
which  sets  it  apart  from  the  rest  of  Asia.  Its  unifying  characteristics  in- 
clude similarities  in  geographic  structure,  climate,  economic  activities, 
culture,  and  history.  With  an  area  of  more  than  3.5  million  square  miles 
South  and  Southeast  Asia  is  larger  than  the  United  States.  In  contrast 
with  other  hot  wet  regions  which  typically  are  thinly  peopled,  South  and 
Southeast  Asia  is  one  of  the  most  heavily  populated  areas  in  the  world.  It 
had  an  estimated  population  of  approximately  650  million  in  1953,  or  one 
quarter  of  the  world  total  on  6  per  cent  of  the  earth's  surface.  This  com- 
pares with  170  million  on  the  11.5  million  square  miles  of  hot  wet  regions 
outside  Asia.1  South  Asia,  the  largest  and  most  populous  of  the  two  re- 
gions embraces  an  area  of  more  than  1.8  million  square  miles  and  has 
more  than  450  million  people.  The  principal  countries  of  South  Asia  are 
India,  Pakistan,  Ceylon,  and  Afghanistan.  (See  Table  21-1.)  Other  politi- 
cal units  include  independent  Nepal  and  Bhutan  and  small  Portu- 
guese enclaves.  Pakistan  comprises  two  territories  separated  by  a  dis- 
tance of  nearly  1,000  miles.  This  unique  political  phenomenon  arose 
out  of  the  provisions  of  the  Indian  Independence  Act  of  1947  which  ended 
British  rule  in  India  and  provided  for  the  establishment  of  the  Dominion 
of  India  and  the  Dominion  of  Pakistan.  The  political  boundaries  of  the 
new  states  were  fixed  primarily  along  cultural— especially  religious— and 
linguistic  ethnic  lines.  Areas  predominantly  Hindu  became  Indian  and 
Moslem  areas  Pakistan.  They  make  little  economic  or  geographic  sense. 
The  distribution  of  the  two  religions  in  former  British  India  was  such  as 

1  P.  Gourou,  The  Tropical  World  (London,  1952),  p.  2. 


SOUTH  AND  SOUTHEAST  ASIA 


645 


to  result  in  a  divided  Pakistan  state.  Of  the  two  zones  which  make  up 

what  has  now  become  the  Republic  of  Pakistan,  East  Pakistan  with  42 

million  people  crowded  in  an  area  one-sixth  the  size  of  West  Pakistan  is 

the  most  important. 

TABLE  21-1 

South  and  Southeast  Asia:   Area  Population  and  Population  Density 
of  Principal  Countries,   1953 


POPULATION 

COUNTRY 

TOTAL  AREA  a 
(  SQUARE  MILES  ) 

POPULATION  b 
(  THOUSANDS  ) 

DENSITY 

( per  square 
mile) 

South  Asia 

Afghanistan 
India 
Pakistan 
Ceylon 

230,888 

1,269,591 

365,893 

25,330 

12,000(1951) 
372,000 
75,842  ( 1951 ) 
8,155 

52 
293 
207 
321 

Southeast  Asia 

Burma 

Thailand 

Indochina 

Malaya 

Indonesia 

Philippines 

261,600 
197,659 
272,355 
52,286 
735,268 
115,600 

19,045 
19,556 
30,000 
6,829 
78,163(1952) 
21,039 

73 
99 
110 
131 
106 
182 

a  United  Nations,   Statistical   Yearbook,    1953. 

b  United  Nations,  Population  and  Vital  Statistics  Reports,   Series  A   (New  York,   January,    1955). 

Southeast  Asia  has  an  area  of  roughly  1.6  million  square  miles  and  a 
population  of  more  than  200  million.  It  includes  Laos,  Cambodia,  Viet  Nam, 
Burma,  and  Thailand  on  the  broad  Indochina  peninsula,  Malaya  on  the 
narrow  Malay  peninsula,  and  the  Indonesian  and  Philippine  archipelagoes 
east  and  southeast  of  the  mainland.  Viet  Nam  was  divided  by  a  provisional 
military  demarcation  line  as  a  result  of  the  Geneva  Conference  of  July 
1954.  The  northern  part  comprising  60,000  square  miles  and  roughly  13 
million  people  is  controlled  by  the  Communist  Viet  Minh.  Free  Viet  Nam 
has  a  republican  form  of  government. 

South  and  Southeast  Asia  has  an  average  population  density  of  almost 
200  persons  per  square  mile.  This  is  very  high  for  a  predominantly  agri- 
cultural region,  exceeding  a  number  of  industrialized  countries  including 
the  United  States.  Population  densities  vary  widely  from  country  to  coun- 
try. In  general  the  Indian  subcontinent  is  overpopulated  while  Southeast 
Asia  is  underpopulated.  Almost  half  of  India's  population  lives  on  14.5 
per  cent  of  the  total  area  with  a  density  of  755  to  the  square  mile.  How- 
ever, Southeast  Asia  has  some  of  the  most  densely  populated  agricultural 


646       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

regions  in  the  world.  Java  and  Madura  (Madoera)  in  Indonesia  for  ex- 
ample, have  more  than  1,000  inhabitants  per  square  mile  and  the  Tonkin 
Delta  in  North  Viet  Nam  more  than  1,100. 

Most  of  the  people  of  South  and  Southeast  Asia  live  in  villages  and 
small  market  towns.  The  number  of  persons  living  in  cities  of  more  than 
50,000  is  only  a  small  fraction  of  the  total  population.  Rural  settlements 
tend  to  be  highly  concentrated  in  the  river  valleys,  deltas,  and  low-lying 
plains  like  the  Ganges  Valley  in  India,  the  Red  River  and  Mekong  deltas 
of  North  Viet  Nam  and  Cambodia,  the  Menam  delta  of  Thailand,  and  the 
Irrawaddy  delta  of  Burma.2  Population  density  in  these  areas  reaches 
2,000  per  mile.  Adjacent  areas  are  often  quite  sparsely  populated  for  a 
variety  of  reasons  including  the  cultural  habits  of  the  natives,  less  favor- 
able soils  and  malarial  infestation.  Thus  the  outer  islands  of  Indonesia 
have  a  population  density  of  under  60  persons  per  square  mile  as  com- 
pared with  Java  and  Madura's  1,100.  Except  for  Tonkin,  Annam,  and 
fringe  areas  along  the  coast,  the  Indochinese  peninsula's  population  den- 
sity is  under  25  persons  per  square  mile. 

South  and  Southeast  Asia  is  characterized  by  high  birth  rates  and  de- 
clining but  still  high  death  rates.  Population  is  currently  estimated  to  be 
growing  at  a  rate  of  somewhat  more  than  1.25  per  cent  per  year  in  South 
Asia  as  against  1.6  per  cent  in  Southeast  Asia.  Declining  death  rates  accord- 
ing to  United  Nations  estimates  may  raise  the  growth  rate  to  as  high  as 
1.83  to  2.32  per  cent  per  annum  by  1980.  This  would  result  in  a  popula- 
tion in  excess  of  1  billion  in  1980. 

GEOGRAPHY  AND  CLIMATE 

South  Asia  lies  entirely  north  of  the  equator  and  half  of  the  Indian  sub- 
continent lies  outside  the  tropics  in  the  Temperate  Zone.  Except  for  the 
northern  tip  of  Burma  all  of  Southeast  Asia  is  in  the  Tropical  Zone  extend- 
ing to  10  degrees  above  the  equator.  The  Indian  subcontinent  has  the 
following  three  main  geographic  divisions:  3  (a)  The  northern  mountain 
wall  with  elevations  of  more  than  3,000  feet,  ( b )  a  lowland  alluvial  area 
with  an  elevation  of  generally  under  500  feet  which  extends  in  a  band 
120  to  200  miles  wide  completely  across  northern  India,  east  and  west, 
and  has  an  area  of  300,000  square  miles,4  and  (c)  the  plateau  of  the 
Indian  peninsula  with  an  area  of  about  one  million  square  miles  and  ele- 

2  United  Nations,  Economic  Survey  of  Asia  and  the  Far  East  (New  York,  1950), 
p.  36. 

3  L.  D.  Stamp,  Asia:  A  Regional  Geography,  11th  ed.  (London,  1952),  pp.  13-14. 

4  J.  E.  Spencer,  Asia  East  by  South  (New  York,  John  Wiley  &  Sons,  1954),  p.  4. 


SOUTH  AND  SOUTHEAST  ASIA  647 

vations  of  3,000  to  1,000  feet  sloping  from  the  West  to  the  East.  Between 
the  Eastern  and  Western  edges  of  this  plateau  are  narrow  coastal  plains. 

The  northern  mountain  barrier  has  served  in  many  ways  to  keep  India 
a  land  apart.  For  all  practical  purposes  India  is  accessible  only  by  sea  and 
by  air.  It  has  no  rail  connections  with  other  countries  of  Asia.  The  lowland 
alluvial  plain  is  one  of  the  most  fertile  areas  on  the  earth's  surface,  which 
largely  accounts  for  its  dense  population.  The  peninsula  has  poorer  soils 
and  less  favorable  water  conditions  for  irrigation  than  the  alluvial  plain. 
Here  population  is  concentrated  mainly  on  the  coastal  plains. 

Southeast  Asia  like  India  displays  considerable  variation  in  its  physical 
features.  In  general  the  terrain  of  the  region  is  hilly  and  mountainous. 
Much  of  the  territory  of  Indochinese  peninsula  and  Thailand  is  wild  and 
rugged.  Mountain  ranges  extend  throughout  the  length  of  the  Malayan 
peninsula  into  Indonesia.  As  a  result  Malaya  has  few  stretches  of  level 
ground  and  no  less  than  two-thirds  of  Java  is  upland  or  mountainous.  The 
ruggedness  of  the  terrain  makes  overland  transport  extremely  difficult,  so 
that  water  transport  is  of  primary  importance.  Much  of  the  soil  is  infertile 
and  is  covered  with  dense  equatorial  forest.  Swamps  and  marshes  are  fre- 
quent along  the  coast.  Scattered  throughout  the  area,  however,  are  fertile 
regions  of  lowland  with  large  stretches  of  alluvial  soil  which,  as  mentioned 
above,  are  the  chief  centers  of  population.  Other  fertile  areas,  chiefly  in 
the  Philippines  and  Indonesia,  have  resulted  from  ash  of  extinct  volcanoes 
mixing  with  the  soil. 

The  climate  of  South  and  Southeast  Asia  is  tropical  even  though 
roughly  half  of  the  Indian  subcontinent  is  outside  the  tropical  belt.  The 
reason  for  this  is  that  the  Himalayas  form  a  great  climatic  barrier  that 
protects  India  from  the  cold  winter  winds  of  Central  Asia. 

South  and  Southeast  Asia  is  predominantly  a  monsoon  zone.  Summers 
are  the  rainy  season  almost  everywhere,  except  in  the  equatorial  regions 
where  seasonal  differences  are  less  marked  and  rain  is  fairly  abundant  at 
all  times.  In  the  region  of  the  monsoons  expanding  hot  air  creates  low 
pressure  areas  on  the  mainland  each  spring.  In  early  June  moist  air  moves 
landward  from  the  sea  to  equalize  the  pressure.  As  the  air  moves  across 
the  land  it  brings  rain  for  a  period  of  almost  four  months.  The  monsoons 
account  for  80  to  90  per  cent  of  the  total  precipitation.  During  other 
seasons  there  is  very  little  rain.  The  amount  of  rainfall  varies  widely  from 
region  to  region  depending  chiefly  on  differences  in  relief  in  relation  to 
wind  direction. 

The  monsoon  plays  a  vital  role  in  South  and  Southeast  Asia's  agricul- 
ture. For  example,  80  per  cent  of  India's  crop  land  depends  on  the  mon- 


648       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

soon  for  water.  It  feeds  large  rivers  for  irrigation.  It  permits  a  fairly  long 
growing  season.  If  the  monsoon  fails,  as  it  periodically  does,  famine  may 
ensue. 

ECONOMIC  AND  STRATEGIC  SIGNIFICANCE 

South  and  Southeast  Asia  plays  an  important  role  in  the  world  econ- 
omy. In  1953,  the  region  accounted  for  roughly  6.5  per  cent  of  the  total 
value  of  Free  World  trade.  It  is  a  major  producer  of  a  number  of  so-called 
"key  materials,"  notably  natural  rubber,  tin,  mica,  titanium,  and  manga- 
nese.5 (See  Table  21-2  and  Fig.  21-1.)  Most  of  the  region's  output  of  these 
products  is  exported  and  represents  a  large  share  of  the  requirements  of 
Western  Europe  and  the  United  States.  The  area  is  also  a  dominant  or 
large  world  supplier  of  many  other  important  raw  materials  and  foodstuffs. 

TABLE  21-2 

South  and  Southeast  Asia: 
Relative  Importance  as  Producer  of  Key  Materials  * 


SHARE  OF  FREE 

COMMODITY 

WORLD  OUTPUT 
(1950) 

COUNTRIES 

Natural  rubber 

89  per  cent 

Malaya,    Indonesia,   Ceylon,   Thailand 

Tin  (metal) 

62 

Malaya,  Indonesia,  Thailand 

Mica 

46 

India,  Pakistan 

Titanium 

30 

India,  Pakistan 

Manganese  (ore) 

26 

India,  Pakistan 

Graphite 

11 

Ceylon 

Bauxite 

7 

Indonesia 

Petroleum 

3 

Indonesia 

*  The   President's   Materials   Policy   Commission,   Resources  For  Freedom,   Vol.    1    (Washington,    D.    C, 
June,    1952),    pp.    9S-100. 

It  supplies  the  bulk  of  the  Free  World's  requirements  of  jute  and  burlap, 
manila  hemp,  tea,  copra  and  coconut  oil,  and  varying  amounts  of  a  large 
variety  of  other  tropical  products  such  as  lac  and  other  gums,  spices,  palm 
oil,  sugar,  and  quinine.  The  economic  vulnerability  of  the  West  to  the  loss 
of  these  supplies  has  been  reduced  as  a  result  of  the  development  of  syn- 
thetics, more  efficient  utilization  of  materials,  the  opening  up  of  alterna- 
tive sources  of  supply,  and  the  accumulation  of  strategic  stockpiles. 
Nonetheless  the  economic  burden  of  such  a  loss  would  still  be  consider- 
able. 

South  and  Southeast  Asia  is  of  particular  economic  importance  to  the 
former  European  colonial  powers,  especially  the  United  Kingdom  and  the 

5  The   President's   Materials   Policy   Commission,    Resources  For  Freedom,   Vol.    1 
(Washington,  D.  C,  June,  1952),  pp.  98-100. 


SOUTH  AND  SOUTHEAST  ASIA  649 

Netherlands.  While  independence  has  operated  to  circumscribe  the  eco- 
nomic activities  of  foreign  nationals  in  South  and  Southeast  Asia,  it  has 
not  radically  altered  the  area's  traditional  pattern  of  trade.  As  before  the 
war  the  largest  share  of  South  and  Southeast  Asia's  trade  is  with  the 
metropoles  or  affiliated  currency  areas.  India,  Pakistan,  Burma,  and  Cey- 
lon have  remained  members  of  the  sterling  area.  Laos,  Cambodia,  and 
Viet  Nam  are  in  the  franc  area,  and  the  Philippine  peso  is  linked  to  the 
dollar.  Malaya  is  the  United  Kingdom's  largest  source  of  dollar  earnings. 
Singapore,  in  its  outstanding  entrepot  role  for  the  region,  is  a  large  source 
of  service  income  for  British  concerns. 

Japan's  economic  well-being,  as  a  result  of  the  loss  of  its  empire,  is 
much  more  dependent  on  South  and  Southeast  Asia  than  before  World 
War  II.  South  and  Southeast  Asia  now  provides  a  market  for  almost  40 
per  cent  of  Japan's  exports,  and  supplies  approximately  30  per  cent  of  its 
imports.  As  mentioned  in  Chapter  16,  Japan's  serious  postwar  balance-of- 
payments  difficulties  would  become  almost  hopeless  if  trade  with  South 
and  Southeast  Asia  were  cut  off. 

The  importance  of  South  and  Southeast  Asia  to  the  security  of  the  rest 
of  the  Free  World  hardly  requires  more  than  brief  mention.  If  the  area 
fell  under  the  control  of  unfriendly  powers  the  United  States  outer  de- 
fenses in  the  Pacific  would  be  seriously  breached.  A  path  to  Australia 
would  be  opened  across  the  discontinuous  land  bridge  of  the  Indonesian 
Islands.  British  control  of  the  Indian  Ocean  which  is  vital  for  the  defense 
of  Southwest  Asia  and  Africa  would  be  jeopardized.  Finally,  if  the  man- 
power and  resources  of  the  area  were  effectively  organized  by  a  ruthless 
authoritarian  power,  as  the  Communists  have  done  in  China,  the  balance 
of  world  power  might  in  time  overwhelmingly  shift  against  the  West. 

RESOURCES 

South  and  Southeast  Asia's  over-all  resource  picture  in  relation  to  area 
and  population  is  not  too  favorable.  With  a  population  in  excess  of  600 
million,  average  density  in  1953  was  roughly  220  per  square  mile  or 
almost  five  times  the  world's  average.  As  described  elsewhere,  areas  of 
greatest  population  pressure  are  the  Indian  subcontinent  and  Java.  Much 
of  Southeast  Asia,  by  contrast,  is  underpopulated  with  large  areas  of 
potentially  productive  land  available  for  cultivation. 

The  region's  heavy  population  density  is  not  offset  by  any  unusual 
endowment  in  other  natural  resources.  South  and  Southeast  Asia's  mineral 
resources,  while  fairly  diversified,  appear  to  be  modest.  They  warrant  no 


650        THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

particular  optimism  regarding  the  potentialities  of  the  area  for  industrial 
development. 

Agricultural  Land.  Comparison  of  population  with  arable  or  actual 
land  under  cultivation  is  of  course  much  more  meaningful  than  compari- 
son with  total  land  area  since  only  part  of  the  land  is  usable  for  the  grow- 
ing of  food  and  raw  materials.  As  shown  in  Table  21-3,  South  and  South- 
east Asia  with  less  than  one  acre  of  cultivated  land  per  head  of  population, 
is  at  the  bottom  of  the  world  scale  with  respect  to  arable  land  per  capita. 

TABLE  21-3 
Areas  of  Cultivated  Land  Per  Head  of  Population  * 

ACRES  PER  HEAD 

2/2  or  more  North  and  South  America,  Australia,  New  Zealand,  Eastern 

Europe  (except  Czechoslovakia),  U.S.S.R. 

1  to  2  Western  and  Central  Europe,  except  Switzerland,  Holland, 

and  Belgium 

Marginal  Czechoslovakia,   Austria,   Italy,   Western  Germany 

Below  1  United   Kingdom,   Belgium,   Holland,   Switzerland 

India,  China,  Japan  and  much  of  Southeast  Asia,  Egypt 

*  J.   Russell,   World  Population  and  World  Food  Supplies   (London,    1954),  p.    16. 

Moreover  much  of  the  land  is  lacking  in  nitrogen  and  phosphate  and  is 
without  dependable  water.  Even  the  countries  of  Western  and  Central 
Europe,  which  are  much  more  highly  industrialized  and  depend  on  im- 
ports to  cover  many  of  their  requirements  for  food  and  agricultural  raw 
materials,  have  up  to  two  and  one-half  times  the  land  area  per  capita  of 
South  and  Southeast  Asia.  Because  of  its  low  per  capita  farm  area  the 
only  way  the  region  can  come  close  to  feeding  itself  is  by  producing  an 
almost  wholly  vegetarian  diet.  Animal  food  production  requires  much 
more  land  than  vegetable  food.  An  acre  of  land  will  yield  up  to  3000 
pounds  of  bread  or  10  tons  of  potatoes  but  only  100  to  200  pounds  of 
meat.6  By  force  of  necessity,  therefore,  South  and  Southeast  Asia  must 
devote  most  of  the  cultivated  area  to  cereal  production. 

As  shown  in  Table  21-4  the  quantity  of  arable  land  varies  considerably 
from  country  to  country  ranging  from  a  low  of  about  one-third  of  an  acre 
in  Indonesia  to  more  than  one  acre  for  Burma.  These  differences  should 
not  be  taken  too  literally,  however,  because  of  possible  inaccuracies  in 
the  country's  classification  of  what  constitutes  arable  land.  Double-crop- 
ping in  some  areas  also  affects  the  significance  of  the  figures. 

6  Ibid.,  p.  16. 


SOUTH  AND  SOUTHEAST  ASIA 


651 


TABLE  21-4 
South  and  Southeast  Asia:   Arable  and  Potentially  Productive  Land  Per  Capita 


COUNTRY 

PERIOD 

ARABLE  LAND 
(  MILLIONS 
OF  ACRES ) 

ARABLE  LAND 
PER  CAPITA 
(  IN  ACRES ) 

POTENTIALLY 

PRODUCTIVE 

(  MILLIONS 

OF  ACRES) 

India  a 

1950 

324.5 

0.87 

98.4 

Pakistan  b 

1948 

51.2 

0.68 

22.2 

Ceylon 

1951 

36.3 

0.44 

2.8 

Afghanistan 

1948 

6.2  c 

0.52 

6.9 

Philippines 

1951 

16.5 " 

0.78 

12.2 

Indonesia 

1947 

27.2 

0,35 

Malaya 

1951 

5.2 

0.76 

2.4 

Burma 

1950 

21.1 

1.10 

19,3 

Indochina 

1951 

18.7  d 

0.62 

21.9 

Thailand 

1949 

11.7  e 

0.84 

Totals 

518.6 

0.81 

a  Including   all   of   Kashmir. 
b  Excludes  Baluchistan. 
c  Excludes  fallow. 

d  Total  agricultural  areas  including  permanent  meadows  and  pastures. 
e  Main  crops  only. 

*  United   Nations,    Food   and   Agricultural   Organization,    Yearbook   of   Food   and   Agricultural   Statistics, 
1952,  Vol.  6,  Part  1. 


Even  if  all  of  the  so-called  potentially  productive  land  of  the  region 
was  brought  into  cultivation,  the  amount  of  arable  land  per  capita  would 
still  be  only  slightly  more  than  one  acre.  In  point  of  fact,  however,  much 
of  this  land,  particularly  in  India,  can  be  reclaimed  only  at  great  cost. 
Only  the  Philippines,  Burma,  Indochina,  and  Thailand  still  have  large 
unexploited  areas  of  good  agricultural  land.  China  with  its  teeming  mil- 
lions may  be  sorely  tempted  to  move  into  these  areas  sometime  in  the 
future  in  order  to  relieve  the  growing  pressure  on  its  strained  land  re- 
sources. 

Mineral  Resources.7  Exact  knowledge  of  the  mineral  resources  of  South 
and  Southeast  Asia  is  lacking,  since  the  area  has  not  yet  been  adequately 
surveyed.  However,  the  geology  of  the  region  is  sufficiently  well-known 
as  to  make  any  sensational  new  mineral  discoveries  unlikely  (Fig.  21-1). 
Coal  and  lignite  reserves  amount  to  less  than  5  per  cent  of  the  world  total, 
petroleum  reserves  to  less  than  2  per  cent,  and  water  power  reserves  to 
about  15  per  cent.  The  only  metals  found  in  significant  amounts  in  relation 
to  the  world  total  are  tin,  manganese,  bauxite,  iron  ore,  and  titanium. 


7  The  materials  used  in  this  section  were  taken  from  United  Nations,  Development 
of  Mineral  Resources  In  Asia  and  The  Far  East  (Bangkok,  1953). 


ra  [3  0 


652 


SOUTH  AND  SOUTHEAST  ASIA  653 

Only  India  has  the  iron  ore  and  coal  reserves  required  to  support  a 
large  steel  industry.  India  has  immense  iron  ore  reserves  estimated  at 
10,000  million  tons,  of  which  as  much  as  half  has  an  iron  content  of  60 
per  cent.  India  also  has  the  bulk  of  the  area's  high-grade  coal,  including 
coking  coal,  although  here  its  reserve  position  is  much  less  favorable  than 
with  respect  to  iron  ore.  Reserves  are  estimated  at  5,000  to  6,000  million 
tons,  of  which,  however,  less  than  1,000  million  tons  is  of  coking  quality. 
Much  of  this  reserve  is  now  inaccessible  and  coking  coal  could  become 
a  problem  with  a  rapid  speed-up  in  India's  industrialization.  While  coal 
is  found  in  most  of  the  other  countries  of  the  area,  much  of  it  is  poor 
quality,  chiefly  lignite.  Indonesia  and  the  Philippines  have  large  iron  ore 
reserves,  but  these  have  a  high  nickel  and  chromium  content  which  has 
to  be  eliminated  before  the  ore  can  be  of  any  commercial  value. 

The  area  is  well-provided  with  such  ferro-alloys  as  tungsten,  manga- 
nese, and  titanium  and  is  moderately  endowed  with  reserves  of  molyb- 
denum, chromium,  and  vanadium.  Except  for  tin,  South  and  Southeast 
Asia  is  deficient  in  non-ferrous  metals.  Limited  amounts  of  antimony  are 
available  in  most  countries.  Small  quantities  of  copper  are  to  be  found  in 
the  Philippines,  India,  and  Burma.  Lead  and  zinc  reserves  still  remain 
untapped  in  Burma. 

Both  India  and  Indonesia  have  the  bauxite  reserves  required  to  estab- 
lish an  aluminum  industry,  provided  cheap  power  can  be  provided.  Rich 
magnesite  reserves  have  also  been  identified  in  both  countries.  Ceylon 
has  sizable  reserves  of  high-grade  graphite  and  India  of  muscovite  bloc 
mica.  No  significant  amounts  of  uranium-bearing  mineral  deposits  have 
been  discovered  but  the  region  abounds  in  beach  sands  containing  mona- 
zite,  which  after  uranium  may  be  the  most  important  source  of  fissionable 
materials.  The  area  is  deficient  in  native  sulphur  required  for  a  chemical 
industry  but  has  some  pyrites  and  gypsum. 

Petroleum  is  found  in  significant  quantities  in  Indonesia,  British  Bor- 
neo, and  Burma,  although  known  reserves  are  small  in  relation  to  the 
world  total.  Indonesia's  oil  reserves  of  about  one  billion  barrels  are 
roughly  1  per  cent  of  the  world  total.  Burma's  petroleum  supplies  will  be 
just  about  sufficient  to  cover  its  growing  needs. 

While  many  parts  of  the  region  lack  adequate  coal  and  petroleum, 
virtually  every  country,  and  in  particular  India,  has  a  huge  water  power 
potential  which  has  been  almost  untouched.  These  hydraulic  resources 
are  not  always  located  in  areas  where  the  need  for  power  is  greatest  and 
their  development  will  require  large-scale  investments.  Nonetheless  they 
could  meet  a  sizable  share  of  the  region's  future  electric  power  needs. 


654        THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 
BASIC  ECONOMIC  CHARACTERISTICS 

The  most  pervasive  economic  characteristic  of  South  and  Southeast 
Asia  is  its  poverty.  With  more  than  one-quarter  of  the  world's  population, 
the  area  accounts  for  only  about  6  per  cent  of  total  production.  Levels  of 
living  everywhere  are  at  or  close  to  minimum  subsistence  levels,  averag- 
ing less  than  $75  per  capita.  As  a  result  only  a  very  small  margin  of  pro- 
duction can  be  spared  for  investment.  For  much  of  the  region  the  level 
of  investment  is  just  sufficient  to  take  care  of  the  growth  of  population 
so  that  living  standards  are  stationary  or  increasing  only  very  slowly. 

The  economy  of  South  and  Southeast  Asia  is  predominantly  agricul- 
tural. The  rural  population  represents  anywhere  from  70  to  90  per  cent 
of  the  total.  Industrial  development  has  been  limited  and  outside  of  India 
has  been  confined  chiefly  to  mining,  the  processing  of  primary  products 
for  export,  and  small-scale  (including  handicraft)  production  of  con- 
sumer goods  for  domestic  use.  Manufacturing  and  construction  for  most 
countries  of  the  region  account  for  less  than  15  per  cent  of  national  in- 
come as  compared  with  50  per  cent  or  more  for  agriculture.  Before  the 
war  a  considerable  share  of  the  capital  required  for  financing  industrial 
development  was  provided  by  overseas  investors,  principally  European. 
Now  most  of  the  capital  is  mobilized  locally,  in  large  part  by  the  govern- 
ments. Except  for  the  Chinese,  however,  the  number  of  foreigners  di- 
rectly engaged  in  the  economic  activities  of  the  region  was  relatively 
limited.  The  overseas  Chinese,  by  contrast,  are  of  considerable  numerical 
importance  in  Southeast  Asia,  especially  in  Malaya,  the  Philippines,  and 
Thailand.  They  play  an  economic  role  considerably  greater  than  even 
their  numerical  importance  suggests  through  their  extensive  control  of 
the  retail  and  export-import  trade  of  the  area.  The  success  of  the  overseas 
Chinese  and  their  dual-citizenship  status  has  aroused  considerable  resent- 
ment among  local  people  and  governments,  and  has  generated  a  variety 
of  legislative  enactments  designed  to  curb  their  activities. 

While  large  plantations  producing  mainly  commercial  crops  for  export 
occur  in  some  parts  of  the  region,  most  farming  is  of  a  small-scale  sub- 
sistence variety.  The  typical  farm  unit  is  only  2  to  5  acres  as  compared 
with  140  acres  in  the  United  States,  and  is  too  small  to  permit  the  farmer 
and  his  family  to  eke  out  more  than  a  bare  existence.  In  a  number  of 
areas  the  size  of  the  peasant's  plot  will  not  even  support  a  bare  sub- 
sistence. The  principal  crops  are  rice  and  other  grains  which  are  largely 
consumed  on  the  farm.  Commercial  crops  produced  for  export  include 


SOUTH  AND  SOUTHEAST  ASIA  655 

rubber,  tea,  rice,  copra,  jute,  cotton,  and  manila  hemp.  Productivity  in 
agriculture  is  low. 

Population  pressure  is  acute  over  much  of  the  area  including  India, 
Cambodia,  Laos,  Viet  Nam,  South  Burma,  and  in  Java  and  Madura.  More- 
over, these  pressures  have  been  intensified  in  recent  years  as  modern  im- 
provements in  public  health  and  sanitation  have  reduced  the  death  rate 
without  a  corresponding  decrease  in  the  birth  rate.  Since  there  are  very 
few  opportunities  in  industry,  rural  overcrowding,  progressive  fragmenta- 
tion of  farms,  and  underemployment  in  agriculture  is  commonplace.  In 
India,  for  example,  it  has  been  estimated  that  rural  unemployment  and 
underemployment  may  be  as  high  as  80  million.8 

Economic  relations  between  the  countries  of  South  and  Southeast  Asia 
are  limited  by  the  fact  that  their  economies  are  more  competitive  than 
complementary.  All  export  mostly  food  and  raw  materials.  Since  there  is 
little  industrialization  within  the  region  the  raw  materials  exports  go 
principally  to  Japan  and  non-Asiatic  markets.  It  was  the  complementary 
character  of  the  Japanese  and  Southeast  Asian  economies  which  partly 
inspired  Japan's  efforts  in  World  War  II  to  construct  its  "Greater  East 
Asia  Co-Prosperity  Sphere."  Trade  within  the  region  is  limited  primarily 
to  movements  of  rice  from  the  surplus  to  the  deficit  areas,  and  exports  of 
textiles  from  India. 

Exports  lack  diversification.  Two  or  three  products  account  for  two- 
thirds  or  more  of  the  exports  of  most  countries  in  the  area.  These  exports 
are  typically  subject  to  wide  fluctuations  in  price  and  volume  depending 
on  foreign  market  conditions.  The  result  is  equally  wide  movements  in 
the  export  earnings  and  levels  of  income  of  these  countries. 

INDUSTRIAL  DEVELOPMENT 

The  very  limited  character  of  South  and  Southeast  Asia's  industrial 
development  is  strikingly  revealed  by  the  fact  that  in  1948,  the  region 
accounted  for  an  estimated  1.5  per  cent  of  world  mining  and  manufactur- 
ing production.9  This  was  only  about  one-third  of  the  industrial  output 
of  Japan  and  less  than  that  of  Belgium.  India  with  1.2  per  cent  of  the 
world  total  accounted  for  the  bulk  of  the  area's  output  of  minerals  and 
manufactures. 

The  dominant  position  of  India  (cf.  Fig.  21-1,  p.  652)  and  the  small 

8  "India— Progress  and  Plan,"  The  Economist,  January  22,  1955. 

9  United  Nations,  Monthly  Bulletin  of  Statistics,  April,  1951. 


CM 

in 


s 
u 

3 

o 


u 

c 

i 

-o 

lO 

s 

^H 

« 

cm 

^- 

_es 

W 

"C 

- 

7. 

PQ 

3 

<; 

C 

i— i 

H 

C3 


3 
0 
-r. 

-3 
B 
03 


3 
O 
C/3 


H 
Z 

W 

w 


z  # 

O  03 
H    Z 

h  a 
c  < 
o    >< 


03  - — - 

W  03 

H  Z 

<!  O 

P  H 


W 

w 

H 

03 


W 

2 
c 

z 

o 

- 


5  * 


o 
o 


p 

H 

z 
p 

c 
u 


o  oo 

O  00 

O  00 

CD^IO 

co" 


Efl 


o 


P  «?  £    H 
cm  OS  2 

r-iin  — - 

W3 


CO 

in 

CD 


oo 

CD 
i— I 

co 


o 

CO 


cm 
cm 


00 

o 

CM 
CM 


I       I 


CM 


CO    TfH 

in  tj< 
co  in 


O    Tf< 

CD 

CO  CM 

00 

Gi  CD 

CM 

C5 


00 

o 

CO 


oo 

CO- 


co 


CO 

o 


o 
oo 


O  CM 
CM   i— I 

in  i— i 
coin 


cm  o  o 

CD  O  CM 

r— I  CO  <— I 

CD" 


"tf  o 

o  o 

0C  CD 

co" 
co 


Cl-i"0 

1  ° 

oo  Tt< 

(Nl 

in  "3  CD 

in  £  en 

1    CO 

CM   CM 

.  CO 

CM 

-—   o 
c  — 

CJ}_ 

3  T3 

o 
co 

C3 


CM 

co 


CM 

in 

oo 


c 

CS 

a 

C/3 

— 

pM 

H 

03 

hH    Ph 


CO 

U 


O 

CO 

C 

M 

w 

.2 

oa 

O 

pq 

CO 

e 

CO 

_H 

'&H 

c 

V3 

D-, 

o 

t3 

3 

pq 

Ph 

<$  -.  G 
>•.  2  « 

^2  £  ^3 


3 

.EZ 


C   •  — 


O 

£ 


7T  *3 


>u 


C 


.a  >. 

£  ° 

to 

s-c    . 

■  -*   ■*-'    t/: 

c  X  ° 

•■  M    m 

Cfl     O     CJ 

>,^e  -a 

MM"" 


U*5 

C  .2 
o  -e 

'3  c 
3  S 


2fflhi 


«  g  H  2  5 

g  pq  £  p,  h 


656 


SOUTH  AND  SOUTHEAST  ASIA  657 

amount  of  industrialization  in  the  rest  of  the  area  is  further  highlighted  by 
the  production  data  shown  in  Table  21-5.  In  1952,  India's  coal  production 
was  twelve  times  that  of  the  rest  of  the  region  combined  and  its  output  of 
electricity  roughly  three  times  as  great.  It  had  the  only  steel  industry.  Its 
textile  industry  not  only  dwarfed  that  of  the  rest  of  South  and  Southeast 
Asia  but  has  become  a  major  factor  in  the  world  export  market.  Only  India 
produces  heavy  machinery  and  equipment  like  locomotives  and  railway 
cars.  It  has  the  only  significant  chemical  industry.  Despite  its  considerable 
industrialization  relative  to  the  rest  of  the  region,  India's  economy  is  still 
overwhelmingly  agricultural.  Factory  employment  in  manufactures  and 
mining  in  1952  amounted  to  only  about  2.5  million  workers.  In  1950, 
mining  and  manufacturing  and  construction  accounted  for  only  15  per 
cent  of  the  net  domestic  product  as  against  50  per  cent  in  agriculture. 
Per  capita  consumption  of  commercial  energy  was  0.10  metric  tons  coal 
equivalent,  or  only  one-eighth  that  of  Japan.  Moreover,  light  industries 
are  of  major  importance.  Thus  in  1952,  approximately  two-fifths  of  the 
entire  industrial  labor  force  of  India  was  employed  in  the  cotton  and  jute 
mills. 

In  the  other  countries  of  South  and  Southeast  Asia,  factory  industry 
consists  chiefly  of  plants  processing  agricultural  and  mineral  products 
mainly  for  export.  These  include  rice  mills  in  Burma,  Cambodia,  Laos, 
Viet  Nam,  and  Thailand,  oil  refineries  in  Indonesia,  tin  smelters,  vegetable 
oil  and  rubber  processing  plants  in  Malaya,  and  sugar  and  coconut  oil 
mills  in  the  Philippines.  In  addition,  most  countries  of  the  region  manufac- 
ture a  considerable  variety  of  consumer  goods  like  ceramics,  glass,  matches, 
soap,  cigarettes,  paper  and  canned  foods.  All  have  small-scale  metal- 
working  industries  capable  of  making  simple  tools  and  equipment  and  of 
doing  repair  work.  In  all  countries  including  India  handicrafts  still  account 
for  a  considerable  share  of  total  output  of  manufactures. 

Relative  to  its  area  and  population  South  and  Southeast  Asia  has  a 
poorly  developed  inland  transportation  system.  Only  India,  which  ac- 
counts for  about  two-thirds  of  the  length  of  railway  lines  for  the  entire 
region,  can  boast  of  a  reasonably  well-developed  and  efficient  rail  system. 
The  development  of  this  network  has  contributed  significantly  to  India's 
economic  and  political  unification.  It  has  been  an  important  factor  in 
facilitating  the  movement  of  food  from  surplus  to  deficit  areas  in  times 
of  local  crop  failures,  thereby  greatly  reducing  the  frequency  and  severity 
of  famines  which  have  plagued  India  in  the  past.  But  even  in  India,  the 
railway  network  is  by  no  means  adequate  to  service  the  country's  growing 
requirements.  Freight  movements  frequently  involve  carriage  both  by 


658       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

rail  and  coastal  vessel,  resulting  in  costly  loading  and  unloading  charges, 
because  of  the  overburdened  rail  system.  The  exploitation  of  valuable 
mineral  resources  has  been  handicapped  by  the  inability  of  the  rail  sys- 
tem to  move  the  ore  from  the  mines. 

Elsewhere  in  South  and  Southeast  Asia  water  transport  both  inland  and 
coastal  has  played  a  much  more  significant  role  than  land  transport  in  the 
region's  economic  development.  In  Burma  the  "linear  build  of  the  coun- 
try, traversed  by  the  Irrawaddy,  has  meant  an  easy  development  of  water 
transport.  Native  traffic  in  considerable  volume  has  flowed  along  the 
Irrawaddy,  the  Chindwin,  and  the  Sittang  for  centuries,  as  well  as  along 
the  whole  coastal  fringe."  10  Similarly  in  Thailand  the  waterways  have 
long  carried  the  bulk  of  the  local  transportation.  Coastal  shipping  is  the 
primary  form  of  transport  in  the  Philippines  and  Indonesia.  Intra-regional 
transport  is  almost  wholly  by  sea  since  rail  or  highway  connections  be- 
tween countries,  except  as  between  India  and  Pakistan,  are  either  very 
inadequate  or  wholly  lacking.  A  considerable  amount  of  this  traffic  is 
moved  by  small  coastal  vessels.  A  few  countries  have  developed  their 
own  merchant  marines.  India  has  a  merchant  fleet  of  almost  half  a  million 
gross  registered  tons  of  vessels  larger  than  100  tons.  Its  shipyards  are 
capable  of  building  large  oceangoing  ships.  Pakistan  and  the  Philippines 
have  merchant  fleets  of  between  150,000  and  200,000  gross  registered 
tons. 

Because  of  poor  land  connections  the  development  of  civil  aviation  in 
South  and  Southeast  Asia  has  been  very  rapid  since  the  war.  Air  freight 
expressed  in  ton-kilometers  increased  fourfold  in  India  from  1948  to  1952. 
Large  though  less  spectacular  increases  were  registered  in  other  countries 
of  the  region.  Most  of  the  countries  of  South  and  Southeast  Asia  have 
established  their  own  airlines. 

AGRICULTURE 

The  pattern  of  agriculture  in  South  and  Southeast  Asia  shows  consider- 
able diversity.  Most  widespread  is  permanent  or  sedentary  farming 
which  involves  the  intensive  cultivation  of  a  given  plot  of  land  on  a  semi- 
subsistence  basis.  Shifting  subsistence  agriculture  is  practiced  on  a  much 
more  limited  scale,  chiefly  in  the  rougher  uplands,  and  accounts  for  5  to 
10  per  cent  of  the  area  under  cultivation  in  most  countries.  This  migratory 
form  of  cultivation  involves  the  clearing  and  planting  of  plots  of  land  for 
a  period  of  two  or  three  years  until  the  fertility  of  the  soil  is  greatly 

10  J.  E.  Spencer,  Asia,  East  by  South  (New  York,  1954),  p.  218. 


SOUTH  AND  SOUTHEAST  ASIA  659 

reduced  and  then  moving  on  and  repeating  the  process  in  a  new  site. 
Finally,  there  is  cash-cropping,  largely  for  export,  both  by  small  individual 
farmers  and  large  plantations. 

Food  crops  account  for  roughly  three-quarters  of  the  acreage  under 
cultivation  in  all  South  and  Southeast  Asia  countries  except  Malaya  and 
Ceylon.  Of  the  food  crops  grains,  chiefly  rice,  are  of  overwhelming  im- 
portance. Wheat,  maize,  millet,  and  sorghum  are  grown  in  significant 
amounts  only  in  India  and  Pakistan.  Grains  supplemented  by  potatoes, 
pulses,  and  sugar  are  the  backbone  of  the  native  diet. 

Although  growing  food  is  the  principal  economic  activity  of  South  and 
Southeast  Asia,  the  area  has  experienced  great  difficulties  since  the  war 
in  expanding  food  output  as  rapidly  as  population.  In  1953-54  per  capita 
food  production  was  10  per  cent  below  prewar  levels,  whereas  in  North 
America  and  Western  Europe  it  was  higher  by  19  per  cent  and  7  per  cent 
respectively.  Before  the  war  South  and  Southeast  Asia  had  a  sizable  grain 
surplus,  mostly  rice.  Thailand,  Burma,  and  Indochina,  Asia's  rice  bowl, 
with  exports  of  milled  rice  in  excess  of  6  million  metric  tons  met  the  im- 
port requirements  of  the  traditional  grain-deficit  countries,  India,  Ceylon, 
Indonesia,  and  Malaya,  and  in  addition  exported  more  than  2  million  tons 
outside  the  region.  Since  World  War  II  South  and  Southeast  Asia  has 
been  a  large  grain-deficit  area  partly  as  a  result  of  the  reduced  availabili- 
ties of  rice  from  the  "rice  bowl"  countries  and  partly  because  of  the  in- 
creased requirements  of  the  traditional  deficit  countries.  In  1953  this  deficit 
still  exceeded  2.5  million  metric  tons.  In  the  past  few  years  most  of  the 
countries  of  South  and  Southeast  Asia  have  come  to  recognize  the  serious 
nature  of  their  food  position,  and  have  given  increasing  attention  to  the 
problem  of  expanding  food  supplies.  These  efforts  have  achieved  a  fair 
measure  of  success  and  have  sharply  reduced  the  region's  grain  deficit 
from  the  1951  peak  levels.  The  present  food  position  of  the  area  is  how- 
ever still  precarious.  With  the  population  of  South  and  Southeast  Asia 
increasing  by  more  than  10  million  persons  annually,  the  area  cannot  afford 
to  relax  its  efforts  to  expand  food  output. 

As  mentioned  elsewhere,  South  and  Southeast  Asia  also  produces  a 
wide  variety  of  tropical  products,  chiefly  for  export.  For  most  countries, 
with  the  notable  exception  of  Ceylon  and  Malaya  where  the  ratio  is  much 
higher,  the  acreage  given  to  commercial  crops  is  about  10  to  15  per  cent 
of  the  total.  Approximately  90  per  cent  of  the  world's  supply  of  natural 
rubber  comes  from  South  and  Southeast  Asia.  Other  products  of  which 
the  area  is  major  world  supplier  include  vegetable  oils,  fibres,  spices,  and 
tea  (see  Table  21-6). 


660        THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 


TABLE  21-6 

South  and  Southeast  Asia: 
Selected  Agricultural  Exports  As  Percentage  of  World  Total 


COMMODITY 

PERCENTAGE  SHARE 

(1952) 

PRINCIPAL    EXPORTERS 

Sugar 
Copra 
Groundnut  oil 

7 
75 
77 

per  cent 

Philippines 

Philippines,   Indonesia,   Ceylon 

Pakistan,  India 

Linseed  oil 

22 

India 

Coconut  oil 
Palm  oil 

63 
32 

Philippines,  Ceylon 
Indonesia,  Malaya 

Castor  oil 

50 

India 

Tea 

90 

India,  Ceylon,  Indonesia 

Pepper 

75 

India,  Indonesia,  Borneo 

Cotton 

12 

Pakistan,  India 

Raw  jute 

95 

Pakistan 

Abaca 

80 

Philippines 

Reference  already  has  been  made  to  the  low  productivity  of  agriculture 
in  South  and  Southeast  Asia.  Yields  per  unit  of  land  are  considerably 
below  other  countries  employing  intensive  agricultural  methods.  The 
production  of  wheat  per  acre  in  India  and  of  rice  throughout  the  region 
is  barely  one-third  that  of  Japan.  Cotton  yields  per  acre  in  India  and 
Pakistan  are  one-third  to  two-thirds  those  in  the  United  States.  Yields  per 
worker  in  agriculture  as  compared  with  more  developed  countries  are 
still  lower. 

Many  factors  contribute  to  these  low  yields.  The  use  of  inferior  and 
unirrigated  soils  is  of  major  importance.  Other  factors  include  the  inade- 
quate use  of  fertilizers,  the  lack  of  mechanical  equipment,  the  land  tenure 
system,  overcrowding,  and  unscientific  farm  methods. 

South  and  Southeast  Asia  as  mentioned  above  is  largely  dependent  for 
its  water  supply  on  the  relatively  brief  monsoons.  The  amount  and  reli- 
ability of  the  monsoon  rains  varies  widely  from  season  to  season  in  many 
areas  causing  wide  fluctuations  in  crop  output.  Considerable  precipitation 
is  lost  as  a  result  of  the  rapid  run-off  of  torrential  downpours  and  large 
areas  are  subject  to  flooding.  Extensive  recourse  has  been  had  to  irrigation 
and  drainage  projects  to  meet  the  problem  of  ensuring  the  proper  amount 
of  water  at  the  right  time.  Dykes  are  widely  employed  to  contain  the 
flood  flow.  Much  land  is  irrigated  by  artificial  canals  leading  from 
dammed-up  rivers.  Tanks  and  reservoirs  in  the  upper  reaches  of  many 
rivers  have  been  used  for  centuries  to  store  water  for  irrigation  purposes. 
Wells  also  are  tapped  for  subsurface  water.  In  recent  years  some  coun- 


SOUTH  AND  SOUTHEAST  ASIA  661 

tries,  notably  India,  have  embarked  on  vast  multi-purpose  projects  of  the 
Tennessee  Valley  Authority  type  which  will  provide  flood  control  and 
irrigation  for  millions  of  acres  as  well  as  electric  power. 

In  1950  more  than  81  million  acres  of  land  in  South  and  Southeast  Asia 
were  irrigated.  This  represented  roughly  25  per  cent  of  the  area  under 
principal  crops.  Any  significant  increase  in  agricultural  output  in  the  area, 
particularly  in  India,  will  require  a  large  expansion  of  irrigated  crop 
lands.  This  fact  generally  has  been  recognized  with  the  result  that  most 
development  plans  give  a  high  priority  to  irrigation  projects.  In  the  first 
two  years  of  the  five-year  development  plan  which  was  started  in  1952, 
irrigation  was  extended  to  2.25  million  acres  in  India.  Thailand  has  a 
major  irrigation  project  under  way  at  Chainat  which  will  provide  regular 
water  supply  to  an  area  of  2.4  million  acres. 

The  development  of  the  Bhakra-Nangal  canal  irrigation  system  in  India 
has  been  a  major  source  of  international  friction  between  India  and 
Pakistan.11  On  July  15,  1954,  Prime  Minister  Mohammed  Ali  of  Pakistan 
described  the  opening  of  the  canal  as  a  "potential  threat  to  peace  in  the 
subcontinent."  12  According  to  Pakistani  engineers  the  677  mile  Bhakra- 
Nangal  irrigation  system,  by  diverting  water  from  the  Sutlej  river  which 
flows  into  Pakistan,  will  dry  up  the  canals  which  irrigate  Pakistan's  5,000,- 
000  acre  granary  in  the  Punjab  Province.  After  long  and  often  bitter 
negotiations  India  agreed  to  help  Pakistan  finance  the  development  of 
alternative  water  sources  in  accordance  with  recommendations  made  by 
the  International  Bank  for  Reconstruction  and  Development. 

Fertilizer  consumption  in  South  and  Southeast  Asia  is  extremely  low. 
In  1951  to  1952,  South  and  Southeast  Asia  with  50  times  as  much  arable 
land  as  Japan  consumed  only  about  one-quarter  as  much  nitrogenous 
fertilizer.  Fertilizer  plants  are  being  constructed  in  a  number  of  countries 
to  meet  the  deficiency  but  a  tremendous  gap  still  remains  to  be  filled. 

Animal  power,  chiefly  buffaloes,  provides  the  main  source  of  farm 
energy.  Farm  implements  are  of  the  most  primitive  types.  In  1949,  India 
and  Pakistan  together  employed  an  estimated  10,000  tractors  in  agricul- 
ture or  fewer  than  in  Finland. 

The  land  tenure  system  by  weakening  incentives  is  a  serious  obstacle 
to  raising  productivity  in  agriculture.  Farm  tenancy  still  exists  on  a  con- 
siderable scale  in  many  parts  of  the  region.  In  1950  over  two-thirds  of 
the  farming  population  of  India  were  tenant  cultivators  and  agricultural 
laborers.  Tenancy  is  a  serious  problem  in  South  Vietnam  and  in  the  newly 

11  See  p.  100. 

12  As  reported  in  the  New  York  Times  of  July  16,  1954. 


662       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

settled  lower  Menam  delta  in  Thailand.  About  35  per  cent  of  the  farming 
population  of  the  Philippines  were  tenants  in  1950.  In  densely  populated 
Central  Luzon,  tenancy  occurs  on  about  88  per  cent  of  the  cultivable 
land.  Rents  are  high,  usually  half  or  more  of  the  gross  produce.  Tenants 
have  little  incentive  to  improve  their  farms  ( 1 )  since  most  of  the  increase 
in  output  is  usually  siphoned  off  by  the  landlord  in  the  form  of  higher 
rents,  and  (2)  they  often  have  no  security  of  tenure.  While  legislation 
has  been  passed  in  a  number  of  countries  to  reduce  tenancy  and  correct 
some  of  its  worse  abuses,  the  governments  are  hampered  in  carrying  out 
these  measures  by  a  lack  of  funds  to  reimburse  landlords  and  resistance 
of  landholders. 

Most  of  the  farming  population  is  permanently  debt-ridden.  Since  their 
land  affords  them  only  a  bare  hand-to-mouth  subsistence,  they  have  no 
reserve  of  capital  to  meet  emergencies  like  crop  failures,  deaths,  wed- 
dings, and  so  on.  Loans  are  usually  only  available  at  exorbitant  interest 
rates  ranging,  up  to  100  per  cent  per  annum,  from  landlords  or  money- 
lenders, since  no  satisfactory  systems  have  been  developed  to  provide 
rural  credit  on  reasonable  terms.  Once  a  farmer  falls  under  the  grasp  of 
a  moneylender  he  very  rarely  escapes  and  he  frequently  ends  up  a  tenant 
on  his  own  land. 

These  are  only  some  of  the  more  serious  features  of  the  land  tenure 
system  in  South  and  Southeast  Asia.  It  is  small  wonder  therefore  that  the 
system  breeds  improvidence  and  inefficiency.  No  less  serious  than  the 
adverse  economic  effects  of  the  land  tenure  system  are  the  disruptive 
political  effects.  Inequitable  land  tenure  systems  have  been  important 
sources  of  agrarian  unrest  in  a  number  of  countries  in  the  region,  the  two 
most  outstanding  examples  being  the  Philippines  and  Communist  Viet- 
nam. The  promise  of  land  reform  is  an  issue  which  has  great  appeal  to  the 
tenant  who  cherishes  the  opportunity  to  own  his  own  piece  of  land.  It  is 
not  surprising  therefore  that  "land  for  the  peasants"  is  one  of  the  most 
potent  propaganda  weapons  of  the  Communists  in  many  parts  of  South 
and  Southeast  Asia. 

FUTURE  ECONOMIC  PROSPECTS 

The  countries  of  South  and  Southeast  Asia  are  very  conscious  of  their 
depressed  economic  status  and  are  making  serious  efforts  to  break  with 
the  poverty  of  the  past.  Virtually  all  governments  have  prepared  blue- 
prints outlining  programs  covering  a  period  of  years  to  accelerate  their 
country's  economic  growth.  All  except  Afghanistan  are  members  of  the 


SOUTH  AND  SOUTHEAST  ASIA  663 

Colombo  Plan,13  created  in  January,  1950,  to  provide  a  framework  for 
international  co-operative  effort  in  promoting  the  economic  development 
of  the  region.  Members  outside  South  and  Southeast  Asia  are  Great  Brit- 
ain, the  United  States,  New  Zealand,  Australia,  Canada,  and  Japan.  The 
Colombo  Plan  arrangement  is  essentially  an  informal  one.  It  has  no  au- 
thority over  individual  members.  Its  primary  purpose  is  to  provide  a 
vehicle  for  the  exchange  of  information  as  to  the  status  and  progress  of 
the  national  development  programs  in  South  and  Southeast  Asia.  It  also 
serves  as  a  channel  for  aid  furnished  by  some  member  countries  outside 
the  area.  Thus  in  1950  Australia  pledged  approximately  £  A  31.25  million 
to  countries  of  South  and  Southeast  Asia  through  the  Colombo  Plan  and 
Canada  appropriated  $133.4  million  through  1955-56.  Some  technical  as- 
sistance is  exchanged  by  member  countries  under  a  Technical  Co-opera- 
tion Scheme. 

The  individual  national  economic  development  programs  generally 
cover  a  three-to-six-year  period.  They  are  fairly  modest  in  their  objectives. 
They  call  for  a  gradual  increase  in  the  rate  of  investment,  an  increase  in 
total  production  somewhat  more  rapid  than  the  growth  of  population, 
and  only  very  moderate  increases  in  per  capita  consumption.  In  almost 
every  case  the  government  has  been  assuming  a  major  responsibility  for 
new  investment  (generally  50  per  cent  or  more  of  the  total).  Major  em- 
phasis is  on  agriculture  and  basic  services  like  electric  power  and  trans- 
portation. 

For  some  countries  these  development  plans  are  still  only  paper  plans, 
and  little  progress  has  been  made  in  implementing  them,  largely  because 
of  unsettled  internal  political  conditions  as  in  Indonesia  or  Viet  Nam. 
Where  countries  have  made  substantial  progress,  notably  in  India,  Burma, 
the  Philippines,  and  Thailand  there  nonetheless  have  been  delays  because 
of  programming  difficulties,  shortages  of  qualified  senior  personnel,  and 
similar  problems.  Lack  of  adequate  resources  to  finance  investment  has 
been  a  major  bottleneck  in  virtually  every  country.  This  lack  of  capital 
may  well  be  the  most  intractable  obstacle  to  sustained  economic  progress 
in  the  region. 

The  problem  of  inadequate  resources  may  be  less  serious  in  the  fore- 
seeable future  for  Southeast  Asia  than  for  South  Asia.  Southeast  Asia 
except  for  Indonesia  is  still  relatively  underpopulated.  It  produces  a 
large  food  surplus  and  still  has  sizable  areas  of  good  agricultural  land  to 
be  opened  up.  Government  profits  from  exports  of  rice  have  provided  and 
can  continue  to  provide  a  good  source  of  income  to  finance  development 

13  See  pp.  286-289. 


664       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

projects.  In  South  Asia,  in  India  and  Pakistan,  the  situation  is  different. 
The  pressure  of  population  on  resources  is  already  great  and  there  is 
relatively  little  room  for  expansion.  Yet  population  is  rising  at  the  rate  of 
1.5  per  cent  per  annum  and  may  increase  to  2  per  cent  in  another  decade 
as  a  result  of  expected  reduction  in  the  death  rate.  Living  standards  are 
so  low  that  it  is  extremely  difficult  to  divert  more  resources  from  con- 
sumption to  investment.  If  the  goals  of  India's  first  five-year  plan,  ending 
March  1956,  were  to  be  met  on  schedule,  savings  would  still  only  repre- 
sent about  7  per  cent  of  total  production.  This  is  only  slightly  more  than 
enough  to  meet  the  needs  of  the  expanding  population.  The  Indian  pic- 
ture is  by  no  means  all  dark.  India  possesses  a  stable  government  and  an 
efficient  and  honest  civil  service.  It  is  showing  a  strong  determination  to 
speed  up  its  economic  growth.  Its  mineral  resources  will  support  a  sub- 
stantially higher  level  of  industrial  output  than  at  present.  Agricultural 
productivity  is  low  and  offers  substantial  opportunities  for  improvement. 
The  Government  is  one  of  the  first  to  officially  support  programs  to  control 
population.  Whether  these  positive  factors  will  be  sufficient  to  overcome 
the  considerable  obstacles  to  India's  economic  development,  particularly 
the  shortage  of  capital,  remains  to  be  seen. 

Pakistan  from  its  inception  as  an  independent  nation  has  been  con- 
fronted with  much  greater  obstacles  to  economic  growth  than  India.  It 
has  had  to  face  the  serious  handicap  of  being  divided  into  two  widely 
separated  parts  (cf.  Fig.  2-3,  p.  35).  It  received  the  smallest  share  of 
former  United  India's  natural  resources  and  administrative  and  technical 
skills.  It  had  to  shoulder  the  heavy  costs  of  a  huge  refugee  problem.  Un- 
der the  circumstances  it  is  not  surprising  that  Pakistan's  economic  progress 
has  been  slow.  It  is  still  too  early  to  tell  whether  or  not  Pakistan  can  estab- 
lish a  solid  economic  base  from  which  sustained  economic  growth  can 
proceed. 

Communist  China,  starting  from  a  considerably  lower  level  than  India, 
has  achieved  a  relatively  high  rate  of  savings  and  investment  in  a  few 
years  if  its  official  statistics  can  be  accepted  as  reliable.  But  Communist 
China  is  an  authoritarian  state  with  a  ruthless  disregard  for  human  needs 
and  values.  The  essentially  democratic  countries  of  South  and  Southeast 
Asia  cannot  readily  impose  greater  sacrifices  on  the  mass  of  the  popula- 
tion without  running  grave  political  risks.  But  if  the  region  fails  to  achieve 
economic  growth  by  democratic  methods,  it  may  in  desperation  decide 
to  emulate  the  Communist  pattern.  This  is  the  danger  which  confronts  the 
Free  World  in  South  and  Southeast  Asia. 


CHAPTER 


22 


Latin  America 


Latin  America's  economic  and  strategic  importance  to  the  Free  World 
at  the  present  time,  particularly  to  the  United  States,  derives  largely  from 
its  role  as  a  major  supplier  of  essential  foodstuffs  and  raw  materials,  as 
well  as  from  its  location  in  relation  to  vital  lines  of  communication,  such 
as  the  Panama  Canal  and  the  Caribbean  Sea.  Economic  relations  between 
the  United  States  and  Latin  America  are  a  frequent  source  of  friction. 
However,  politically  it  is  aligned  with  the  West,  although  it  is  not  free 
from  or  immune  to  Communist  penetration,  as  the  Guatemala  experience 
showed.  It  makes  little  military  contribution  to  the  Free  World  system 
of  collective  security  because  of  its  limited  capabilities. 

Latin  America's  importance  lies  chiefly  in  its  rapidly  growing  potential. 
Its  population  is  growing  faster  than  that  of  any  other  region  in  the 
world.  If  present  demographic  trends  continue  Latin  America  could  have 
a  population  of  500  million  within  the  next  fifty  years,  or  double  the  an- 
ticipated population  of  the  United  States  and  Canada.1  Latin  America 
is  the  one  major  underdeveloped  area  in  the  Free  World  which  is  under- 
going rapid  economic  development  and  where  the  prospects  for  continued 
economic  growth  are  favorable.  Moreover  the  desire  for  economic  im- 
provement is  one  of  the  most  powerful  forces  operating  in  Latin  America 
today.  If  present  trends  continue,  Latin  America  is  bound  to  play  an  in- 
creasing role  in  world  affairs  by  virtue  of  the  sheer  growth  of  its  popula- 
tion and  expanding  economic  capabilities. 

1  Report  to  the  President,  United  States-Latin  American  Relations,  Department  of 
State  Bulletin  (  November  23,  1953). 

665 


666       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

AREA  AND  POPULATION 

Latin  America  extends  for  a  distance  of  more  than  6,000  miles  from 
the  Rio  Grande,  separating  the  United  States  and  Mexico,  to  Cape  Horn 
at  the  southern  extremity  of  Argentina.  Including  the  West  Indies  it  em- 
braces an  area  in  excess  of  8  million  square  miles  or  two  and  two-thirds 
that  of  the  United  States.  Latin  America's  population  in  1953  of  approxi- 
mately 172  million  about  equalled  the  combined  populations  of  English- 
speaking  Canada  and  the  United  States.  It  includes  twenty  republics  and 
a  number  of  European  colonial  possessions  in  the  West  Indies  and  the 
Guianas.  This  chapter  will  deal  primarily  with  the  independent  countries 
of  Latin  America,  since  the  colonies  are  much  closer  politically  and  eco- 
nomically to  the  old  world  than  to  the  Western  Hemisphere. 

Latin  America  is  thinly  populated  with  an  average  density  of  22  persons 
per  square  mile.  With  19  per  cent  of  the  habitable  land  area  of  the  world 
it  has  only  about  7  per  cent  of  the  world's  population.  Among  the  major 
regions  of  the  world,  only  Australia  and  Africa  have  a  lower  population 
density.  Wide  variations  from  this  average  are  found  from  country  to 
country  and  as  between  different  regions  in  the  same  country.  At  one 
extreme  is  Haiti  with  more  than  300  persons  per  square  mile  and  at  the 
other  Paraguay  with  less  than  10.  (See  Table  22-1.)  A  very  few  rural 
areas,  such  as  the  Barbados  in  the  British  West  Indies,  have  population 
densities  similar  to  those  found  in  South  and  Southeast  Asia.  Even  among 
the  most-thickly  peopled  areas  population  density  rarely  exceeds  125  per 
square  mile  and  usually  is  less.  In  general,  Middle  America  (Mexico, 
Central  America,  and  the  Caribbean  Islands)  is  more  thickly  populated 
than  South  America.  For  an  underdeveloped  region  Latin  America  shows 
an  unusually  large  concentration  of  population  in  urban  centers.  Five 
cities  have  populations  of  one  million  or  more  and  thirty-nine  have  popu- 
lations between  100,000  and  one  million  2  (cf.  Fig.  6-3,  p.  150). 

The  population  of  Latin  America  shows  great  racial  diversity.  The  main 
components  are  Indians,  whites,  and  Negroes.  The  absence  of  strong  in- 
hibitions against  mixed  marriages  has  resulted  in  the  widespread  mingling 
of  these  three  groups,  so  that  today  more  than  half  the  population  of 
Latin  America  is  of  mixed  heritage,  or  mestizo.  Only  two  countries,  Ar- 
gentina and  Uruguay  in  the  temperate  zones,  have  predominantly  white 
populations.  Elsewhere  the  proportion  of  peoples  of  unmixed  European 
ancestry  is  generally  less  than  15  per  cent.  Pure-blooded  Indians  are  a 

2  P.  E.  James,  Latin  America,  rev.  ed.  (New  York,  1950),  p.  7. 


LATIN  AMERICA 


667 


majority  in  Ecuador,  Peru,  Bolivia,  Paraguay,  and  Guatemala.  Negroes 
predominate  on  most  of  the  Caribbean  Islands.  Natural  factors  such  as 
climate  have  been  important  in  contributing  to  the  low  proportion  of 
whites  to  the  total  population,  particularly  in  the  tropics.  Spanish  and 
Portuguese  colonial  policies  which  favored  quick  exploitive  returns  rather 
than  permanent  settlement  also  had  some  effect. 

TABLE  22-1 
Latin  American  Republics:   Area,  Population  and  Population  Density,   1953  ° 


COUNTRY 


AREA 
( SQUARE  MILES ) 


POPULATION 
(000) 


POPULATION 

DENSITY 

(  PER  SQUARE  MILE  ) 


Venezuela 

352,141 

5,440 

15.4 

Colombia 

439,825 

12,108 

27.5 

Ecuador 

105,510 

3,924 

37.2 

Peru 

506,189 

9,035 

17.9 

Bolivia 

416,040 

3,107 

7.5 

Chile 

286,396 

6,072 

21.2 

Paraguay 

150,516 

1,496 

9.9 

Argentina 

1,072,745 

18,393 

17.1 

Uruguay 

72,172 

2,525 

34.9 

Brazil 

3,286,169 

55,772 

16.9 

Mexico 

758,550 

28,053 

36.9 

Guatemala 

42,044 

3,049 

72.4 

El   Salvador 

13,176 

2,052 

155.7 

Nicaragua 

57,144 

1,166 

20.4 

Honduras 

59,160 

1,564 

26.3 

Costa  Rica 

19,238 

881 

45.7 

Panama 

28,575 

864 

30.2 

Cuba 

44,217 

5,807 

131.3 

Dominican  Republic 

19,129 

2,291 

119.7 

Haiti 

10,700 

7,739,637 

3,227 
166,825 

301.6 

Total 

Av.  21.5 

*  United    Nations,    Statistical    Yearbook,    1954. 

Population  is  growing  most  rapidly  in  Middle  America  and  tropical 
South  America  where  birth  rates  are  high  and  death  rates  are  already 
fairly  low.  During  1949  to  1951  the  average  annual  rate  of  population 
growth  of  mainland  Middle  America  was  2.87  per  cent.  No  figures  are 
available  in  the  same  period  for  tropical  South  America  but  during  1940 
to  1950  the  average  annual  growth  rate  in  this  area  was  2.23  per  cent. 
Growth  rates  are  lower,  under  2  per  cent  per  annum,  in  temperate  South 
America  where  fairly  low  death  rates  are  accompanied  by  declining  birth 
rates.  United  Nations  projections  suggest  the  possibility  of  a  Latin 
American  population  in  excess  of  300  million  by  1980. 


668       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

GEOGRAPHY  AND  CLIMATE  3 

Geographical  factors  have  had  important  economic  and  political  effects 
on  Latin  America's  development.  Latin  America  is  part  of  what  is  loosely 
termed  "the  Western  Hemisphere."  4  However,  while  the  Panama  Canal 
has  linked  the  entire  west  coast  of  South  America  as  well  as  its  northern 
territories  with  both  coasts  of  the  United  States,  the  southeastern  shore 
from  Cape  Sao  Roque  to  the  Plata  river  region  is  almost  as  close  to  Eu- 
rope as  to  the  United  States,  and  is  much  nearer  to  Africa  than  to  either.5 
Roughly  95  per  cent  of  South  America  lies  east  of  New  York  City.  The 
fact  that  South  America  juts  so  far  out  into  the  Atlantic  has  helped  to 
promote  economic,  cultural,  and  political  relations  with  Europe.  It  is  only 
in  the  past  quarter-century  that  Latin  America's  cultural  relations  with 
the  United  States  have  become  closer  than  with  Europe.  At  the  same  time 
South  America's  extreme  southerly  position  has  had  an  over-all  inhibiting 
effect  on  its  relations  with  the  rest  of  the  world  because  the  main  streams 
of  commerce  have  been  east  and  west. 

Although  Latin  America  extends  from  roughly  33  degrees  north  latitude 
to  almost  55  degrees  south  latitude,  approximately  three-quarters  of  it 
lies  in  the  tropics.  The  main  reason  for  this  is  the  triangular  shape  of 
South  America  which  tapers  off  sharply  below  the  tropic  of  Capricorn. 

Latin  America  exhibits  wide  differences  in  topography  and  climate 
which  in  turn  have  significantly  affected  the  pattern  of  economic  develop- 
ment and  settlement.  Middle  America,  connecting  the  United  States  and 
South  America,  is  predominantly  mountainous  with  few  extensive  flat 
areas.  Plains  and  lowlands  are  largely  limited  to  narrow  strips  along  the 
coasts  and  certain  rivers.  Slopes  are  gentler  and  coastal  areas  broader  in 
the  east  than  in  the  west  so  that  the  orientation  of  commerce  eastward 
has  been  facilitated.  The  topography  of  Central  America  has  been  an  im- 
portant fact  in  the  failure  of  the  area  to  achieve  greater  political  and 
economic  cohesiveness.  In  the  Caribbean,  Cuba  is  relatively  level  while 
the  Dominican  Republic  and  Haiti  have  the  rugged  and  mountainous 
terrain  of  the  mainland.  Northern  Mexico  to  the  tropic  of  Cancer  is  arid 
or  semi-arid.  Further  south  rainfall  is  more  plentiful  though  still  inade- 
quate in  many  places.  The  Gulf  and  Caribbean  coasts  are  wetter  than 
the  Pacific  coast.  No  part  of  Cuba  is  deficient  in  moisture  but  semi-arid 
areas  are  found  in  Haiti. 

3  Based  largely  on  P.  E.  James,  Latin  America,  rev.  ed.  (New  York,  1950). 

4  See  p.  258. 

5  L.  L.  Bernis,  The  Latin  American  Policy  of  the  United  States  (New  York,  1943), 
Ch.  1. 


LATIN  AMERICA  669 

While  most  of  Middle  America  is  close  to  or  in  the  Tropical  Zone,  the 
high  elevation  of  much  of  the  region  has  a  significant  moderating  effect 
on  the  temperature.  Mexico  City,  7,500  feet  above  the  Pacific  and  Guate- 
mala City  5,000  feet  above  it,  even  though  in  the  tropics,  have  a  climate 
most  of  the  year  like  spring  in  Southern  California  15  to  20  degrees  to 
the  North.  With  few  exceptions,  the  highlands  are  the  areas  of  greatest 
population  density  in  Middle  America  even  though  low-lying  but  poten- 
tially richer  agricultural  lands  are  available,  as  in  the  Gulf  region  of 
Mexico.  Undoubtedly  the  invigorating  climate  of  the  high  plateau  as 
compared  with  the  hot  unhealthy  lowlands  has  contributed  to  this  pattern 
of  settlement. 

South  America  divides  from  West  to  East  into  three  main  longitudinal 
zones  (1)  the  Cordilleras  of  the  Andes,  (2)  the  lowland  belt  and  (3)  the 
plateaus  of  Guiana  and  Brazil.  The  Andes  form  a  high  mountain  belt  100 
to  400  miles  wide  extending  from  the  Caribbean  in  the  North  to  the  tip 
of  Tierra  del  Fuego  in  the  South.  Over  most  of  this  distance  the  Andes 
rise  close  to  the  coast  leaving  only  very  narrow  coastal  plains.  These 
mountains  have  been  a  major  obstacle  to  the  development  of  communica- 
tions with  the  rest  of  the  continent  and  have  served  to  retard  the  west 
coast's  economic  development.  The  west  coast  has  few  good  harbors  but 
the  opening  up  of  the  Panama  Canal  played  a  vital  role  in  reducing  its 
economic  isolation.  Arable  land  is  limited  to  coastal  valleys  and  high 
plateaus  between  the  mountains. 

The  lowland  belt,  which  includes  the  Orinoco,  and  Amazon  river  val- 
leys, and  the  Chaco  and  Pampas  plains,  is  almost  continuous  from  the 
mouth  of  the  Orinoco  to  the  northern  border  of  Patagonia.  It  embraces 
roughly  half  the  area  of  South  America.  Much  of  this  area  has  few  people, 
particularly  in  the  hot  humid  tropical  latitudes.  The  lowland  plains  meet 
the  Guiana  and  Venezuelan  highlands  in  the  North  and  the  Brazilian 
highlands  in  the  east.  The  former  are  remote  from  the  coast  and  relatively 
unexplored.  The  latter  which  extends  through  most  of  the  length  of  Brazil 
at  an  elevation  of  1,000  to  3,000  feet  support  the  bulk  of  the  country's 
population  and  again  illustrates  the  attraction  of  cooler  highlands  in 
tropical  regions. 

One  other  significant  physical  feature  of  South  America  is  its  vast  river 
system.  The  Amazon,  with  a  drainage  basin  of  almost  three  million  square 
miles,  is  the  largest  river  in  the  world.  The  Orinoco  to  the  north  drains 
an  area  of  possibly  four  hundred  thousand  miles.  However,  fluctuations 
in  water  levels,  rapids  or  falls,  and  other  obstacles  have  impaired  the  use- 
fulness of  these  and  other  rivers  for  water  transportation. 


rfl 

wi 

O 
•— 

c 

7^ 

« 

a, 

Ml 

u 

C 

« 

l^ 

£ 

* - 

-— ■». 

"a 

1C 

o 

■^^ 

u 

„ s 

La 

CO 

V 

a 

■— ' 

c 

•  f\ 

o 

u 

o 

- — - 

,^ 

TT 

in 

i— ( 

— ' 

' — ' 

•  r* 

.« 

E 

3 

> 

C 
1 

*S 

3 

„ — „ 

M 

CO 

3 
U 
- 


"£*S 

a>   C 


fc.  - — ' 

« 

"3  .£ 
•a  - 

-M 
S« .. 

s  ^ 


*"-'  o 

..    M 

0)  ^ 

a® 

s  w 
o     „ 


as 


CD 


u  .55 

"C  H3 

J   <= 
-I 

C    B    B 

U  a  J 

<N  — > 

<M  '^CO 

.  00  iH 


670 


LATIN  AMERICA  671 

Altitude  and  shape  exercise  important  influences  on  the  climate  of 
South  America.  High  altitudes  as  in  Middle  America  counteract  the  effect 
of  latitude  in  the  tropical  regions.  Thus,  on  the  east  coast,  the  Brazilian 
highlands  produce  relatively  cool  climates  for  a  distance  of  400  to  600 
miles  inland  in  an  area  ranging  from  the  Tropic  of  Capricorn  to  within 
ten  degrees  of  the  equator.  Quito,  the  capital  of  Ecuador,  though  almost 
on  the  equator,  with  an  elevation  of  9,000  feet  has  an  average  monthly 
temperature  of  54  degrees  Fahrenheit.  The  tapering  shape  of  South 
America  exposes  the  climate  of  the  southern  part  of  the  continent  to  the 
moderating  influences  of  the  ocean.  As  a  result,  temperatures  are  much 
less  extreme  both  in  summer  and  winter  than  for  the  same  latitudes  in 
North  America. 

Tropical  South  America  generally  has  an  abundance  of  rainfall  and  in 
some  areas,  like  the  Amazon  lowlands,  has  an  excess.  Arid  or  semi-arid 
conditions  obtain  in  Northeast  Brazil  and  in  the  coastal  areas  of  Ecuador, 
Peru,  and  the  Atacama  desert  of  Northern  Chile.  Central  and  Southern 
Chile  have  an  ample  supply  of  rainfall,  while  on  the  eastern  side  of  the 
Andes,  in  Argentina,  arid  and  semi-arid  conditions  prevail  over  most  of 
the  area. 

RESOURCES 

Latin  America  probably  is  the  best-endowed  of  the  major  underdevel- 
oped regions  with  respect  to  physical  resources  (Figs.  22-1,  2).  Except  for 
most  of  the  West  Indies  and  certain  Central  American  countries  like  El 
Salvador,  where  the  pressure  of  population  on  resources  is  acute,  the  area 
is  underpopulated.  Arable  land  per  capita  is  two  or  three  times  greater 
than  in  South  and  Southeast  Asia  and  exceeds  most  countries  in  Africa. 
Moreover,  unused  but  potentially  productive  land  is  at  least  50  per  cent 
of  the  arable  land  area.  Latin  America  has  large  reserves  of  many  of  the 
most  important  minerals  required  to  support  an  industrial  economy.  It  has 
vast  untapped  water  power  resources.  Its  major  deficiency  is  coal.  There  is 
little  doubt  that  Latin  America's  resource  base  will  support  a  much  larger 
population  than  at  present  and  at  rising  living  standards,  provided  the 
capital  can  be  mobilized  to  effectively  exploit  these  resources. 

Agricultural  Land.  According  to  World  Food  and  Agriculture  Organi- 
zation statistics,  arable  land  and  unused  but  potentially  productive  land 
represent  about  5  per  cent  of  the  total  area  of  Latin  America.  The  number 
of  cultivated  acres  is  roughly  1.3  per  capita.  The  cultivation  of  potentially 
productive  land  would  raise  this  figure  to  about  2  acres  per  capita.  This 
figure  is  probably  on  the  low  side,  in  that  considerable  land  now  classed 


672       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

as  "permanent  meadows  and  pastures"  could  be  used  to  raise  crops.  Indi- 
vidual countries  show  wide  variations  from  the  average  in  cultivated  land 
per  capita.  ( See  Table  22-2. )  The  best-endowed  countries  are  Argentina, 
Chile,  Paraguay,  and  Uruguay  in  the  mid-latitudes.  The  humid  Pampa  of 
Argentina  is  one  of  the  best-endowed  meat  and  grain  producing  areas  in 

TABLE  22-2 
Latin  America:   Arable  and  Potentially  Productive  Land  * 


COUNTRY 

PERIOD 

TOTAL 

ARABLE  LAND 

(iNCL.  FALLOW 

AND  ORCHARDS ) 

( 000  ACRES ) 

ARABLE  LAND 
PER  CAPITA 
( 1953  POP. ) 

total  unused 

but  potentially 

productive 

(000  acres) 

Venezuela 

1951 

6,672 

1.23 

583 

Colombia 

1950 

6,029 a 

0.5 

Ecuador b 

1949 

7,413 

2.16 

5,752 

Peru 

1950 

3,954 

0.44 

Bolivia 

1938 

845 

0.3 

Chile 

1942 

8,238 

1.36 

Paraguay 

1947 

3,830 c 

2.56 

Argentina 

1948 

74,130 

4.03 

Uruguay 

1951 

5,046 

2.0 

Brazil 

1947 

46,541 

0.8 

72,390 

Mexico 

1951 

37,065 

1.32 

22,239 

Guatemala 

1950 

3,553 

1.17 

El  Salvador 

1950 

1,349 

0.66 

Nicaragua 

1949 

1,678 

1.44 

7,786 

Honduras 

1951 

2,001 

1.29 

Costa  Pica 

1950 

872d 

1.0 

Panama 

1951 

608 

0.7 

Cuba 

1946 

4,868 

0.84    • 

62 

Dominican  Republic 

1946 

1,680 

0.73 

.    .    . 

Haiti 

1947 

1,137 

0.35 

Total 

217,509 

Av.  1.30 

a  Excludes  fallow. 
b  Excludes  Oriente  Province. 
c  Total   agricultural   area. 
d  Excludes  holdings  of   less   than   0.7   acres. 

*  United   Nations,    Food,   and   Agricultural   Organization,    Yearbook   oj  Food  and   Agricultural  Statistics, 
1952,  Vol.   6,   Part   1. 


the  world.6  The  possession  of  this  rich  natural  resource  was  an  important 
factor  in  the  more  rapid  economic  development  of  Argentina  than  of 
other  parts  of  Latin  America.  While  Latin  America  has  a  relatively  favor- 
able land  base  as  compared  with  other  underdeveloped  areas,  it  is  no- 
where nearly  as  well-endowed  with  good  soils  as  the  United  States.  In 

6  P.  E.  James,  "An  Assessment  of  the  Bole  of  the  Habitat  as  a  Factor  in  Differential 
Economic  Development,"  American  Economic  Review,  Vol.  41,  No.  2  (May,  1951), 
pp.  231-238. 


LATIN  AMERICA  673 

the  United  States  23  per  cent  of  the  total  land  area  is  arable  or  potentially 
productive,  while  the  number  of  acres  cultivated  per  capita  of  population 
is  about  4.  The  main  reason  for  the  substantially  lower  ratio  of  cultivable 
land  in  Latin  America  is  the  existence  of  vast  tropical  rain-forest  areas 
like  the  Amazon  and  the  Orinoco. 

The  Amazon  Valley  is  almost  equal  in  size  to  the  United  States  and 
accounts  for  roughly  two-fifths  of  all  of  South  America.  Yet  it  supports 
a  population  of  under  4  million.  Despite  the  variety  of  its  still  largely 
unexploited  natural  resources,  it  has  yet  to  be  demonstrated  that  the  area 
can  support  a  large  population  at  satisfactory  levels  of  living.  The  sparse 
population  cannot  be  explained  by  the  hot  humid  climate  alone  since 
regions  in  similar  latitudes  of  South  and  Southeast  Asia  are  among  the 
most  densely  populated  in  the  world.  Approximately  two-thirds  of  the 
Amazon  Valley  consists  of  rough  foothills  and  mountains  which  are  ex- 
tremely difficult  for  man  to  penetrate.  This  territory  virtually  rings  an 
almost  flat  inner  basin  of  about  one  million  square  miles.  Transportation 
is  less  of  a  problem  in  this  inner  area  because  of  its  vast  system  of  inter- 
connecting waterways.  However,  here  the  only  soils  suitable  for  intensive 
cultivation  are  the  flood-plains.  A  study  made  in  1952  indicated  that  only 
3  to  4  per  cent  of  the  inner  basin  is  subject  to  inundation.7  Lands  beyond 
the  flood-plain,  despite  their  dense  tropical  vegetation,  have  almost  no 
mineral  nutrient  reserves.  When  cleared  and  cultivated  they  lose  their 
fertility  in  one  or  two  years.  The  lands  above  the  flood-plain  therefore 
offer  little  attraction  to  the  farmer,  since  they  require  shifting  cultivation 
and  will  yield  him  only  a  bare  subsistence.  Their  most  economic  use  may 
be  for  raising  tropical  tree  crops  like  palm  oil.  The  trees  of  the  forest 
themselves  are  of  limited  commercial  value  because  of  the  absence  of 
dense  stands  of  single  species,  particularly  conifers. 

Of  the  30,000  to  40,000  square  miles  of  flood-plain  only  about  500 
square  miles  are  cultivated.  This  area  could  therefore  support  millions  of 
additional  population.  However,  it  would  yield  them  only  the  same 
meager  subsistence  as  the  rice-grower  in  the  rich  delta  regions  of  Asia, 
since  the  farm  family  can  cultivate  only  a  few  acres  with  the  limited 
equipment  at  its  disposal.  Large-scale  operations  would  require  heavy 
capital  investments  in  dykes,  drainage  systems,  and  pumps.  Thus,  Fair- 
field Osborn  concludes,  the  Amazon  Valley  "might  eventually  accommo- 
date forty  or  fifty  million  persons  at  the  bare  subsistence  stage  now 
prevailing."  8  An  alternative  might  be  the  development  of  extensive  plan- 

7  F.  Osborn,  The  Limits  of  the  Earth  ( Boston,  1953),  p.  142. 

8  Ibid.,  p.  145. 


i.i— .i.iiiiwiiw.  n.m» 


Port  of  Spain, 


etown 

Paramaribo 

Cayenne 


200  400  600  Ml 


•1- 

* 

1                      17 

♦      1 

■*"      1       IK 

o    ! 

J.M  •<■ 


Fig.  22-2.  South  America:  Resources:  (1)  coal;  (2)  iron  ore;  (3)  aluminum;  (4)  oil;  (5)  rail- 
road; (6)  Pan-American  Highway;  (7)  mercury;  (8)  silver;  (9)  copper;  (10)  vanadium; 
(11)  manganese;  (12)  platinum;  (13)  tin;  (14)  tungsten;  (15)  gold;  (16)  lead  and  zinc, 
(17)  uranium;  (18)  diamonds. 

674 


LATIN  AMERICA 


675 


tation  operations  like  the  Ford  Company  rubber  plantation  established  in 
the  1930's.  The  failure  of  the  Ford  project,  however,  suggests  that  the 
high  costs  of  attracting  the  required  labor  may  make  it  difficult  to  pro- 
duce commercial  crops  in  the  area  at  competitive  world  prices. 

Countries  in  the  mid-latitudes  possess  the  greatest  possibilities  for  ex- 
panding agricultural  output.  "The  permanent  pastures  of  the  Pampas 
might  become  very  much  more  productive  through  the  increased  use  of 
the  plough  and  the  introduction  of  a  rotation  system  based  on  the  occa- 
sional cultivation  of  the  land  and  improved  varieties  of  grass  and  herbage 
plants,  especially  alfalfa."  9  In  the  tropics  there  are  large  unused  areas 
suitable  for  cattle  raising.  Increased  crop  production,  however,  will  de- 
pend in  considerable  measure  on  more  irrigation. 

Minerals.  (Cf.  Fig.  22-1,  2.)  Latin  America  has  many  minerals  in  more 
than  adequate  quantities.  It  has  a  very  significant  share  of  the  Free 
World's  reserves  of  such  essential  minerals  as  iron  ore,  copper,  lead,  zinc, 
bauxite,  petroleum,  tin  and  tungsten  (see  Table  22-3). 

TABLE  22-3 
Latin  America:   Share  of  Free  World's  Reserves  of  Selected  Minerals  * 


MINERAL 


PERCENTAGE 
SHARE 


PRINCIPAL  COUNTRIES 


Iron  ore  ( 50  per  cent  Fe 

content  or  more ) 
Manganese  ( 45  per  cent  mn  or 

above ) 
Copper  ( contained  metal ) 
Lead  ( contained  metal ) 
Zinc  ( contained  metal ) 
Tin  ( contained  metal ) 
Antimony  ( contained  metal ) 
Bauxite  ( contained  metal ) 
Tungsten  ( contained  metal  ^ 
Native  sulphur 
Mercury 
Petroleum 


40  per  cent  Brazil,  Venezuela,  Chile,  Mexico 

10  per  cent  Brazil,  Cuba 

38  per  cent  Chile 

1 1  per  cent  Peru,  Argentina,  Chile 

9  per  cent  Argentina,  Peru,  Mexico 

10  per  cent  Bolivia 

77  per  cent  Bolivia,  Mexico 

38  per  cent  West  Indies,  Brazil,  Surinam 

18  per  cent  Bolivia,  Brazil,  Peru 

48  per  cent  Chile,  Mexico 

4  per  cent  Mexico 

12  per  cent  Venezuela,  Mexico,  Colombia, 

Peru 


*  The  President's  Materials  Policy  Commission,  Resources  For  Freedom,  Vol.   11,  Ch.   23    (Washington, 
June,   1952). 


Other  minerals  found  in  Latin  America  include  platinum,  vanadium, 
nickel,  bismuth,  and  fluorspar.  Uranium  has  been  found  in  a  number  of 
countries.  Mexico  and  Brazil  appear  to  be  the  best-endowed  with  mineral 

9  F.  L.  McDougall,  "Food  and  Population,"  International  Conciliation,  No.  486, 
publication  of  the  Carnegie  Endowment  For  International  Peace  (New  York,  19523. 
d.  572. 


676       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

resources.  In  general,  however,  the  economic  significance  of  Latin  Amer- 
ica's mineral  resources  has  been  reduced  by  virtue  of  their  distance  from 
industrial  centers,  the  inadequate  transport  system,  and  the  shortage  of 
power.  This  is  especially  true  in  the  case  of  Brazil. 

The  little  coal  found  in  some  countries  of  Latin  America  is  generally 
low-grade  and  not  suitable  for  coking.  Countries  having  the  greatest  en- 
ergy requirements  such  as  Argentina  and  Brazil  frequently  also  lack 
sufficient  petroleum  as  an  alternative  source  of  power.  As  a  result  they 
are  heavily  dependent  on  imported  fuels.  Such  imports  have  been  absorb- 
ing a  growing  share  of  their  limited  foreign  exchange  earnings,  thereby 
restricting  imports  of  capital  equipment  for  economic  development.  Brazil 
and  Argentina  are  seeking  to  solve  this  problem  by  expanding  domestic 
oil  production.  Favorable  geological  formations  suggest  the  existence  of 
large  oil  reserves  in  both  countries.  The  development  of  Latin  America's 
vast  water  power  resources  can  also  provide  needed  energy.  The  hydraulic 
resources  of  Brazil  alone  are  estimated  to  exceed  those  of  the  United 
States.  However,  hydro-electric  projects  require  large  investments  of  capi- 
tal. Furthermore,  there  is  no  substitute  for  coal  in  the  making  of  blast 
furnace  products  and  open  hearth  steel  and  in  the  manufacture  of  certain 
heavy  chemicals,  or  for  petroleum  for  highway  transportation.  Some  relief 
from  the  coal  problem  may  be  provided  as  shipments  of  Latin  American 
iron  ore  to  the  United  States  expand.  Vessels  which  otherwise  might  pro- 
ceed from  the  United  States  in  ballast  can  carry  coal  at  low  transport  costs. 

ECONOMIC  AND  STRATEGIC  IMPORTANCE 

Latin  America  is  of  greater  significance  in  the  world  economy  than  any 
of  the  other  major  underdeveloped  regions.  In  1953  it  accounted  for 
approximately  10  per  cent  of  the  total  value  of  world  trade.  It  is  of  par- 
ticular importance  as  a  trading  partner  of  the  United  States.  Latin 
America  takes  one-fifth  of  all  this  country's  exports  and  supplies  one-third 
of  our  imports.  It  thus  accounts  for  a  substantially  larger  share  of  United 
States  trade  than  all  of  continental  Western  Europe  and  the  United  King- 
dom. It  is  more  important  as  a  market  for  United  States  exports  than  Asia, 
Africa,  and  Oceania  combined. 

Latin  America  is  a  major  world  producer  of  a  wide  variety  of  industrial 
and  agricultural  commodities  ( see  Tarble  22-4 ) ,  most  of  which  are  shipped 
abroad.  Many  of  these  commodities  are  strategic  in  character;  some  thirty 
items  on  the  United  States'  strategic  stockpile  list  come  from  Latin 
America.  Latin  America  provided  20  per  cent  or  more  of  the  total  United 


LATIN  AMERICA 


677 


States  supply  ( 1952 )   of  such  metals  as  copper,  lead,  zinc,  manganese, 

vanadium,  beryllium,  antimony,  and  cadmium.  It  furnishes  various  other 

strategic  metals  like  tin  and  tungsten  in  lesser  but  important  amounts. 

More  than  55  per  cent  of  this  country's  imports  of  crude  petroleum  and 

iron  ore  come  from  Latin  America  and  over  90  per  cent  of  our  aluminum 

imports.  Latin  America  is  of  particular  importance  to  the  United  States 

as  a  source  of  essential  supplies  in  wartime,  since  ( 1 )  it  is  less  vulnerable 

to  enemy  takeover  or  destruction,  and  (2)  lines  of  communications  with 

Latin  America  are  easier  to  maintain  and  protect  than  with  other  overseas 

areas. 

TABLE  22-4 

Latin  American  Republics: 
Share  of  World  Production  of  Selected  Raw  Materials,   1952  ° 


INDUSTRIAL    COMMODITY 

PER  CENT 

AGRICULTURAL  COMMODITY 

PER  CENT 

Tantalite 

52.4 

Henequen 

98.1 

Bauxite 

46.2 

Coffee 

83.3 

Beryllium 

46.2 

Cocoa  beans 

25.1 

Silver 

36.8 

Sugar  cane  and  beet 

15.5 

Bismuth 

34.7 

Sisal  (1951) 

24.3 

Antimony 
Petroleum 

34.4 
18.9 

Flaxseed 
Wool 

21.4 
15.0 

Tin,  mine 

18.9 

Cotton 

12.5 

Zinc,  mine 

16.0 

Cottonseed  (1951) 

12.3 

Fluorspar 
Tungsten 

15.1 
12.9 

Abaca  (1951) 
Cattle   ( number ) 

10.9 
10.1 

Graphite 
Manganese 

12.7 
7.2 

Hogs  (number) 
Corn 

9.8 
9.0 

Molybdenum 

Mercury 

Platinum— group  metals 

7.4 
5.8 
4.9 

Wheat 
Peanuts   (1951) 

3.9 
2.3 

Nickel 

4.7 

*  Foreign  Operations  Administration,  Report  on  the  Economic  Situation  in  Latin  America  (Washington, 
D.  C,  August,   1954),  p.  91. 


Large  amounts  of  foreign  capital,  particularly  United  States  capital, 
are  invested  in  Latin  America.  At  the  end  of  1953,  almost  $7  billion,  or 
roughly  one-third  of  all  United  States  private  investment  abroad,  were 
in  Latin  America.10  These  yielded  a  return  of  roughly  $1  billion  annually. 
Despite  the  large  investments,  Latin-Americans  are  inclined  to  feel  that 
the  United  States  has  not  shown  sufficient  concern  about  their  develop- 
ment problems.  They  are  particularly  resentful  about  the  large  amount 
of  United  States  aid  given  Europe  and  Asia  as  compared  with  Latin 
America.  They  feel  they  are  too  much  taken  for  granted.  Other  major 

10  United  States  Department  of  Commerce,  Survey  of  Current  Business  (May,  1954). 


678       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

investors,  notably  the  United  Kingdom  and  France,  substantially  reduced 
their  investments  in  Latin  America  during  the  interwar  period.  British 
investments  as  of  1951  were  down  to  about  $700  million.11 

The  strategic  importance  of  Latin  America  is  of  course  not  limited  to 
its  role  as  a  supplier  of  essential  materials.  Middle  America  is  on  the  door- 
step of  the  United  States.  Therefore  any  threat  to  the  security  of  the  area 
is  a  direct  threat  to  the  security  of  this  country.  The  Caribbean  countries 
guard  the  approaches  to  the  vital  Panama  Canal.  Parts  of  Latin  America 
can  provide  valuable  air  and  naval  bases  to  protect  American  lines  of 
communication  as  they  did  in  World  War  II.  At  the  present  time  Latin 
America  has  only  very  limited  military  capabilities  to  contribute  to  the 
defense  of  the  Free  World.  But  it  is  an  area  experiencing  very  rapid  popu- 
lation growth  and  considerable  economic  expansion.  An  area  which  may 
have  as  many  as  500  million  people  by  the  year  2000  necessarily  will  play 
an  increasingly  important  role  in  the  international  political  arena  in  the 
coming  years. 

BASIC  ECONOMIC  CHARACTERISTICS 

Probably  the  most  significant  feature  of  the  Latin  American  economy 
has  been  its  rapid  rate  of  growth.  Latin  America  is  not  stagnating  like 
many  other  underdeveloped  regions.  During  the  decade  ending  in  1953  per 
capita  gross  national  product  for  the  region  as  a  whole  has  increased  at  a 
rate  of  more  than  2.5  per  cent  per  annum.  This  compares  with  the  growth 
of  per  capita  income  of  2.1  per  cent  per  annum  in  the  United  States  during 
the  period  1869  to  1952.  Rates  of  investment  averaged  close  to  15  per  cent 
of  gross  national  production  over  the  period  or  only  slightly  less  than  in 
the  more  highly  developed  areas.  While  certain  favorable  and  probably 
nonrecurring  factors  contributed  to  this  impressive  record  of  growth,  this 
postwar  experience  indicates  elements  of  underlying  strength  in  the  Latin 
American  economy. 

Latin  America  is  nonetheless  still  poor.  In  1952  average  per  capita 
gross  national  product  was  only  about  $250.  While  this  is  considerably 
more  than  South  and  Southeast  Asia's  $75  per  person  it  is  far  below  the 
$2,000  for  the  United  States.  Wide  variations  from  the  average  obtain 
from  country  to  country  ( see  Table  22-5 ) .  Argentina  and  Venezuela  with 
per  capita  incomes  in  excess  of  $425  approach  the  lower  end  of  the  scale 
for  industrialized  countries.  Five  countries  with  incomes  of  less  than  $100 

11  Pan-American  Union,  Foreign  Investments  In  Latin  America:  Measures  For  Their 
Expansion  (Washington,  D.  C,  1954),  p.  10. 


LATIN  AMERICA 


679 


per  person  are  close  to  being  on  a  par  with  the  most  impoverished  under- 
developed areas.  Moreover,  since  incomes  are  distributed  very  unequally 
in  Latin  America,  most  of  the  population  has  substantially  lower  incomes 
than  indicated  above.  In  addition  to  low  incomes,  Latin  America  portrays 
all  the  other  typical  characteristics  of  underdeveloped  regions.  Diets  are 
inadequate  in  a  number  of  countries,  productivity  is  low,  educational  fa- 
cilities are  grossly  inadequate,  and  illiteracy  is  widespread.  The  over-all 
death  rate  is  roughly  50  per  cent  higher  than  in  the  United  States,  and  in 
many  countries  large  segments  of  the  population  suffer  from  endemic  de- 
bilitating diseases. 

TABLE  22-5 

Latin  America:   Per  Capita  Gross  National  Product,  1952  ° 
(in  1950  $  U.  S.) 


163 

62 

149 

222 

139 

362 

56 

96 

295 

452 


Argentina 
Bolivia 

430 
66 

Guatemala 
Haiti 

Brazil 

217 

Honduras 

Chile 

296 

Mexico 

Colombia 

215 

Nicaragua 

Costa  Rica 

198 

Panama 

Cuba 

Dominican    Republic 

Ecuador 

El  Salvador 

406 

171 

90 

167 

Paraguay 
Peru" 
Uruguay 
Venezuela 

*  Foreign   Operations  Administration,    op.    cit.,    and    United   Nations,    Department   of   Economic   Affairs, 
Economic  Survey  of  Latin  America,  1953   (New  York,    1954). 

Latin  America  is  still  a  predominantly  agricultural  economy  in  terms  of 
employment  of  the  labor  force.  Moreover,  the  organization  of  agriculture 
is  largely  feudal  in  character  with  large  estates  taking  up  the  greater  part 
of  the  cultivable  land  throughout  the  region.  Of  a  total  active  population 
in  1953  of  33.9  million,  almost  60  per  cent  was  engaged  in  agriculture.12 
Only  Argentina  has  a  larger  labor  force  in  industry  than  in  agriculture. 
However,  industry  because  of  its  greater  productivity  accounts  for  a  larger 
share  of  total  output  than  agriculture. 

Almost  all  countries  are  highly  dependent  on  proceeds  from  exports 
of  a  few  primary  products  to  finance  necessary  imports.  Thus  in  1952 
coffee  accounted  for  60  per  cent  of  the  value  of  Brazil's  exports,  copper 
for  56  per  cent  of  Chile's,  sugar  for  70  per  cent  of  Cuba's,  petroleum  for 
98  per  cent  of  Venezuela's,  and  coffee  for  54  per  cent  of  Central  America's. 
This  high  degree  of  specialization  explains  the  intense  interest  of  Latin 
Americans  in  international  commodity  stabilization  arrangements  for  their 

12  United  Nations,  Department  of  Economic  Affairs,  Economic  Survey  of  Latin 
America,  1953  (New  York,  1954),  p.  23. 


680       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

main  exports.  Intra-regional  trade  is  small,  amounting  to  less  than  10  per 
cent  of  total  trade.  The  principal  reason  is  that  the  economies  of  the  region 
are  largely  competing  rather  than  complementary.  An  additional  factor  is 
the  poor  transport  connections  between  countries. 

TRANSPORTATION 

Few  countries  in  Latin  America,  except  possibly  Argentina,  Chile,  Uru- 
guay and  Venezuela,  and  parts  of  Brazil  and  Mexico,  can  be  said  to  have 
reasonably  well-developed  transportation  systems  (cf.  Figs.  22-1,  2). 
The  lack  of  modern  means  of  transport  over  most  of  Latin  America 
is  a  serious  impediment  to  the  region's  economic  growth.  In  many  parts 
of  Latin  America,  such  as  Ecuador,  "mountainous  terrain  cuts  off  rich 
agricultural  regions  from  population  and  industrial  centers  .  .  .  Better 
highway  rail,  harbor,  inland  waterway,  and  air  transportation  facilities 
will  often  create  conditions  which  would  make  possible  the  develop- 
ment of  mining,  manufacturing,  agricultural  and  other  enterprises  . . ."  13 
While  development  of  transport  is  a  paramount  need  in  Latin  America, 
efforts  to  overcome  this  handicap  are  severely  hampered  by  the  heavy 
costs  imposed  by  such  natural  obstacles  as  the  eastern  plateaus,  the  vast 
Tropical  Zone,  and  the  rugged  Andes. 

Although  the  few  developed  rail  networks  are  limited  to  the  mainland 
east  coast  and  Cuba,  the  railways  account  for  the  bulk  of  the  internal 
traffic  of  most  Latin  American  countries.  The  rail  systems  of  most  coun- 
tries are  short  and  rarely  interconnected.  They  frequently  were  con- 
structed for  the  primary  purpose  of  carrying  raw  materials,  usually 
minerals,  from  the  interior  to  the  ports  for  overseas  shipment.  Few  lines 
run  north  and  south.  Only  in  several  countries  do  rail  lines  have  inter- 
national connections,  like  the  trans-Andine  lines  between  Chile  and 
Argentina.  A  serious  obstacle  to  the  development  of  both  national  and 
international  connections,  in  addition  to  the  terrain,  is  the  absence  of 
standardized  gauges.  In  an  effort  to  promote  Western  Hemisphere  rail- 
way development,  the  American  Republics  have  established  a  Pan- 
American  Railway  Congress  Association. 

Highway  transport  has  been  of  growing  significance  in  recent  years 
and  in  a  few  countries,  notably  Mexico,  rivals  the  rail  system  in  impor- 
tance for  the  carriage  of  interurban  freight.  An  important  reason  for  the 
rapid  growth  of  road  transport  is  the  low  density  of  population  in  many 
areas.  As  a  result  the  volume  of  traffic  frequently  is  not  sufficient  to  war- 

13  Department  of  State,  United  States-Latin  American  Relations  (December,  1953). 


LATIN  AMERICA  681 

rant  the  high  costs  of  constructing  railroads.  By  and  large  the  highway 
system  is  poor.  Only  a  small  percentage  of  the  roads  have  all-weather  sur- 
faces and  paved  highways  are  largely  confined  to  urban  centers  and  their 
environs.  During  the  rainy  season  many  roads  are  impassable.  As  with 
railroads,  natural  obstacles  impede  the  development  of  highways. 

Despite  Latin  America's  excellent  river  system,  inland  water  transport 
in  most  countries  generally  moves  no  more  than  about  10  per  cent  as 
much  cargo  as  the  railways.  Inland  navigation  has  great  potentialities, 
however,  and  could  become  of  increasing  importance  in  the  interior  as 
South  America  is  developed.  Thus  ocean-going  vessels  up  to  7,000  tons 
can  navigate  the  Amazon  up  to  Manaus,  a  distance  of  almost  700  miles 
from  the  Atlantic,  while  vessels  half  that  size  can  navigate  to  the  Peruvian 
port  of  Iquitos,  a  distance  of  almost  2,000  miles.  Furthermore,  water  trans- 
port is  much  cheaper  than  land  transport.  It  costs  less  to  move  cargo  six 
thousand  miles  by  ship  from  Callao,  Lima's  port,  through  the  Panama 
Canal  and  up  the  Amazon  to  eastern  Peru,  than  over  the  500-mile  trans- 
Andes  highway  from  Lima  to  Pucallpa  on  the  Ucayali  river.14 

Most  traffic  between  Latin  American  countries  is  moved  by  coastal 
shipping.  Some  countries,  chiefly  Argentina  and  Brazil,  have  sizable 
coastal  fleets.  In  addition,  the  twenty  Latin  American  Republics  in  1952 
had  more  than  9  million  dead-weight  tons  of  ocean-going  vessels  of  1,000 
tons  or  more.  Of  this  amount,  however,  approximately  6  million  tons  were 
Panamanian  and  Honduran  vessels  owned  by  United  States  interests.  If 
these  are  excluded  Latin  America's  ocean-going  fleet  is  about  3  per  cent 
of  the  world  total.  It  accounts  for  only  a  small  percentage  of  Latin  Amer- 
ica's total  overseas  trade.  Two  countries,  Paraguay  and  Bolivia,  are  land- 
locked. In  the  case  of  Paraguay,  all  its  exports  and  imports  must  pass 
through  Argentina.  As  a  result,  Paraguay  has  been  under  continual  pres- 
sure from  Argentina.15 

INDUSTRIAL  DEVELOPMENT 

Manufacturing  has  expanded  much  more  rapidly  in  Latin  America 
since  the  war  than  other  economic  activities.  Between  1945  and  1952, 
manufacturing  output  including  construction  increased  at  the  rate  of  6.9 
per  cent  per  year  as  compared  with  2.7  per  cent  for  agriculture  and  4.8 
per  cent  for  total  production.  In  1952,  manufactures  and  construction 
accounted  for  roughly  28  per  cent  of  total  production  as  compared  with 


14  Osbom,  op.  cit.,  p.  126. 

15  See  also  p.  197. 


682       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

less  than  24  per  cent  for  agriculture.  However,  manufactures  exceeded 
agricultural  output  in  only  three  countries,  Argentina,  Chile,  and  Mexico 
(see  Table  22-6).  These  countries  together  with  Brazil,  Colombia,  and 
Venezuela  account  for  90  per  cent  of  Latin  America's  industrial  output. 

TABLE  22-6 

Latin  America: 
Relative  Importance  of  Manufactures  in  Selected  Countries,  1952  * 


MANUFACTURING 

AND  CONSTRUCTION 

AGRICULTURE 

OTHER  ACTIVITIES 

AREA 

(  PER  CENT 

(per  CENT 

(  PER  CENT 

OF  TOTAL 

OF  TOTAL 

OF  TOTAL 

OUTPUT ) 

OUTPUT ) 

OUTPUT ) 

Latin  America 

27.9 

23.6 

51.5 

Argentina 

34.3 

29.0 

36.7 

Chile 

24.7 

15.7 

59.6 

Mexico 

20.3 

18.2 

61.5 

*  United  Nations,  Economic  Survey  of  Latin  America,  1951-52. 

A  number  of  countries,  notably  Bolivia,  the  Caribbean  and  Central  Amer- 
ican Republics,  and  Panama  and  Paraguay  have  experienced  relatively 
limited  industrial  development.  In  part  at  least  their  problem  has  been 
the  small  size  of  the  domestic  market.  This  has  led  the  governments  of 
Central  America  to  study  the  possibilities  of  developing  new  activities 
based  on  an  integrated  regional  market.  A  meeting  of  the  Ministers  of 
Economy  held  at  Tegucigalpa  in  August  1952,  agreed  on  the  principles 
involved  in  reciprocity  and  singled  out  potential  industries  where  these 
principles  could  be  applied.16  Thus  far,  however,  no  real  progress  has  been 
made  toward  the  goal  of  regionalization  of  industry.  Industrialization 
probably  has  gone  further  in  Argentina  than  anywhere  else  in  Latin  Amer- 
ica despite  that  country's  deficient  mineral  and  power  base.  Whereas 
private  enterprise  predominates  in  Latin  America,  the  governments  of 
many  countries  are  a  major  source  of  investment  funds.  Thus  at  the  pres- 
ent time  roughly  half  of  all  new  capital  expenditures  in  Argentina,  Vene- 
zuela, and  Mexico  are  made  by  the  Federal  Government. 

As  in  other  underdeveloped  regions,  industrial  output  consists  in  large 
part  of  consumer  goods  for  the  domestic  market,  although  the  processing 
of  foodstuffs  and  the  refining  of  copper,  lead,  and  zinc  for  export  are  of 
some  importance.  Capital  goods  industries  do  not  account  for  more  than 
15  per  cent  of  Latin  America's  industrial  output.  However,  Latin  America 

16  Economic  Commission  for  Latin  America,  Committee  of  Ministers  of  Economy 
on  Economic  Co-operation  in  Central  America,  Report  of  the  First  Sessions. 


LATIN  AMERICA  683 

has  a  sizable  and  growing  steel  industry.  In  1954,  Brazil,  Chile,  and  Mex- 
ico had  a  combined  output  of  crude  steel  in  excess  of  2.0  million  metric- 
tons.  New  mills  were  about  to  be  opened  in  Colombia,  Argentina,  and 
Peru.  Argentina's  San  Nicolas  steel  mill  on  the  Parana  River  will  have  a 
steel  ingot  capacity  of  588,000  metric  tons.  Argentina,  Mexico,  and  Brazil 
have  mechanical  transforming  industries  of  considerable  importance,  pro- 
ducing machinery,  motors,  railway  rolling  stock,  home  appliances,  and 
other  products,  while  Mexico  and  Brazil  also  have  motor  vehicle  assembly 
plants.  The  production  of  construction  materials,  particularly  cement, 
lime,  and  wood,  is  important  in  a  number  of  countries.  Progress  also  has 
been  made  toward  establishing  a  basic  chemical  industry. 

Latin  America's  industrial  development  has  been  hampered  by  the  lack 
of  basic  services,  particularly  electric  power  and,  as  described  elsewhere, 
transport.  Electric  power  is  frequently  so  short  that  in  some  countries  it 
has  had  to  be  rationed.  These  deficiencies  have  prevented  the  establish- 
ment of  new  enterprises  and  impeded  the  efficient  operation  of  existing 
ones.  Private  capital  has  contributed  little  to  meeting  the  shortage  in  basic 
services  because  of  the  investment  habits  of  local  capitalists.  Much  of 
Latin  America's  new  investment  goes  into  fields  like  speculative  commer- 
cial ventures  and  luxury  urban  construction  which  contribute  relatively 
little  to  development.  Consequently  a  good  deal  of  the  responsibility  for 
providing  these  services  has  been  assumed  by  the  governments.  However, 
the  amounts  of  capital  required  are  large  and  commonly  exceed  the  re- 
sources of  the  governments. 

AGRICULTURE 

With  the  exception  of  the  few  countries  noted  above,  agriculture  is  the 
principal  economic  activity  in  Latin  America.  Although  not  land-poor  like 
Southeast  Asia,  Latin  America  nonetheless  has  a  major  land  tenancy  prob- 
lem. In  the  Caribbean  and  South  America,  the  large  estate  dominates  the 
agrarian  structure.  The  large  estate  is  characteristic  of  all  countries  except 
parts  of  Costa  Rica,  El  Salvador,  Haiti,  and  Mexico.  For  Latin  America 
as  a  whole,  individual  landholdings  in  excess  of  15,000  acres  account  for 
about  50  per  cent  of  all  agricultural  land.17  In  Argentina  85  per  cent  of 
the  privately  owned  land  is  in  estates  larger  than  1,250  acres  while  80  per 
cent  of  the  farm  population  own  no  land.  Plantations  are  important  in 
some  regions,  chiefly  in  Central  America  and  the  Caribbean  but  do  not 

17  United  Nations,  Land  Reform:  Defects  in  Agrarian  Structures  as  Obstacles  to 
Economic  Development  (New  York,  1951). 


684       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

dominate  the  economy  as  a  whole.  The  bulk  of  the  rural  population  of 
Latin  America  consists  of  small  tenants,  landless  laborers,  and  small  land- 
owners of  subsistence  farms  with  very  low  living  standards.  In  many 
countries  the  relationship  between  the  tenant  and  the  landlord  is  feudal 
in  character.  In  return  for  the  right  to  cultivate  a  small  piece  of  land  the 
tenant  devotes  a  specified  number  of  days'  labor  per  week  on  the  estate. 
As  in  Southeast  Asia,  the  large  estate,  except  for  the  plantation  which 
practices  intensive  cultivation,  is  a  serious  drag  on  productive  efficiency. 
Moreover,  large  estates  devoted  to  grazing  result  in  serious  under-utili- 
zation  of  land.  Countries  like  Colombia  and  Venezuela,  which  have  ample 
land  resources  to  be  self-sufficient  in  foodstuffs  if  more  intensive  cultiva- 
tion was  practiced,  have  to  import  food  to  feed  their  populations.  "The 
pattern  of  land  utilization  is  .  .  .  the  reverse  of  what  market  conditions  and 
natural  resources  require.  The  hillside  land,  which  is  best  suited  for  pas- 
ture and  woodland,  is  intensively  cultivated  for  subsistence  crops  by  hoe 
culture  which  destroys  the  top  soil,  while  the  valley  floors,  more  suited  for 
arable  cultivation  are  used  for  grazing."  18  Thus  .  .  .  "the  combination  of 
very  extensive  agriculture  and  a  high  degree  of  concentration  of  owner- 
ship prevents  a  fuller  utilization  of  land  resources  and  an  expansion  of 
food  production  for  local  needs,  and  it  depresses  the  living  standard  of  the 
majority  of  the  farm  population."  19 

In  addition  to  its  adverse  economic  effects,  the  system  of  land  tenure 
in  Latin  America  as  in  other  underdeveloped  areas  is  a  serious  source  of 
social  tension.  It  is  considered  the  most  fundamental  issue  in  the  social, 
economic,  and  political  life  of  Ecuador,  Peru,  and  Bolivia.  Political  oppor- 
tunists periodically  exploit  the  land  problem  in  order  to  enlist  broader 
peasant  support  for  their  policies.  The  most  recent  example  was  the  ex- 
propriation of  large  estates  and  the  distribution  of  land,  albeit  limited,  to 
the  peasants  by  the  Communist-dominated  Arbenz  Government  in  Guate- 
mala prior  to  its  overthrow  in  June  1954.  Where  extensive  foreign  owner- 
ship of  plantations  exists,  as  in  Guatemala  and  other  parts  of  Central 
America  and  the  Caribbean,  the  tensions  created  by  the  land  tenure  prob- 
lem are  frequently  heightened.  In  the  West  Indies,  the  plantation  economy 
has  created  "strikes,  riots,  the  burning  of  canes,  and  in  some  colonies  even 
an  uncertainty  from  year  to  year  whether  the  state  of  labour  relations  will 
permit  the  whole  crop  to  be  taken  off."  20 

Only  two  countries  in  Latin  America  have  instituted  broad  agrarian 

18  Ibid.,  p.  20. 

19  Ibid.,  p.  49. 

20  W.  A.  Lewis,  Issues  in  Land  Settlement  Policy,  a  report  to  the  Caribbean  Com- 
mission West  Indian  Conference.  1950. 


LATIN  AMERICA  685 

reform  programs,  Mexico  as  early  as  1915  and  Bolivia  in  August  1953. 
Reform  measures  periodically  have  been  introduced  in  a  number  of  other 
countries  but  nothing  much  has  come  of  them  to  date.  The  major  obstacle 
is  of  course  the  resistance  of  the  powerful  landholders.  This  problem  was 
described  by  the  Government  of  Chile  in  response  to  a  United  Nations 
questionnaire  on  land  reform  as  follows: 


21 


Owing  to  the  economic  and  political  structure  of  the  country,  land  reform 
in  Chile  is  difficult  to  carry  out.  Land  holders  who  would  be  affected  by  any 
action  of  an  economic,  political,  administrative,  legal  or  social  nature  will  vigor- 
ously oppose  its  implementation,  and  their  political  and  economic  influence  is 
very  powerful.  In  spite  of  this,  the  necessary  conditions  are  being  created  in 
Chile  to  initiate  a  land  reform  policy,  which  will  have  to  be  introduced  gradu- 
ally, in  other  words,  with  due  safeguards  but  with  determination. 

While  modern  methods  of  cultivation  are  being  rapidly  introduced  in 
a  number  of  Latin  American  countries,  the  techniques  of  the  peasant 
farmer  are  still  primitive.  His  principal  tools  are  the  hoe  and  the  machete. 
The  use  of  fertilizers  is  quite  limited.  Thus  far  the  employment  of  modern 
equipment,  scientific  techniques,  and  the  use  of  fertilizers  is  largely  con- 
fined to  the  large  plantations  and  estates. 

Before  the  war,  the  growing  of  food  and  agricultural  raw  materials  for 
export  was  almost  as  important  as  for  domestic  consumption.  For  the 
period  1934  to  1938  agricultural  exports  averaged  roughly  45  per  cent  of 
total  agricultural  output.22  Growing  local  requirements  resulting  from  the 
expansion  of  population,  rising  incomes,  and  general  economic  develop- 
ment have  radically  changed  this  relationship.  In  1953,  agricultural  ex- 
ports represented  only  about  one-third  of  total  production.  While  the 
volume  of  Latin  America's  agricultural  output  in  1953  was  approximately 
one-third  higher  than  before  the  war,  virtually  all  of  this  increase  was 
retained  at  home. 

Despite  the  growth  of  agricultural  output,  production  has  not  been  sat- 
isfactory in  relation  to  the  growth  of  population.  On  a  per  capita  basis 
total  agricultural  production  and  food  production  in  1953-54  were  still 
below  prewar.  This  lag  in  agricultural  production  has  resulted  in  consid- 
erable measure  from  the  preoccupation  of  most  Latin  American  govern- 
ments in  the  postwar  years  with  programs  to  speed  up  their  industriali- 
zation. Ill-considered  government  policies  were  adopted  which  favored 
industry  at  the  expense  of  the  agricultural  sector  of  the  economy.  Only 
in  the  past  year  or  two,  with  population  increasing  at  a  rapid  rate,  has 

21  United  Nations,  Progress  in  Land  Reform  (New  York,  1954),  p.  43. 

22  United  Nations,  Economic  Survey  of  Latin  America,  1953,  p.  135. 


686        THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

it  been  recognized  that  agriculture  is  no  less  important  than  industry  for 
Latin  America's  economic  development.  A  number  of  countries,  notably 
Argentina,  Chile,  Mexico,  and  Brazil,  are  now  actively  attempting  to 
stimulate  agricultural  output  by  means  of  various  incentives  and  aids  to 
farmers.  These  policies  are  already  beginning  to  bear  fruit. 

Table  22-7  gives  the  production  of  the  principal  agricultural  crops  cul- 
tivated in  Latin  America  and  the  importance  of  these  crops  in  world  trade. 
Latin  America  is  a  dominant  area  in  the  exports  of  tropical  products  like 
sugar,  coffee,  bananas.  It  is  an  important  supplier  of  meat,  cacao,  cotton, 
and  wool.  Exports  of  grains  are  much  less  important  than  before  the  war, 
in  large  part  because  of  reduced  output  and  export  availabilities  from 
Argentina. 

TABLE  22-7 
Latin  America:   Production  and  Exports  of  Agricultural  Production 


PRODUCTION  a 

(  MILLION 

METRIC  TONS) 

EXPORTS 

AS  PER  CENTb 

COMMODITY 

1948-50 

1952-53 

OF  WORLD  TOTAL  1952 

(AV.) 

(  PROV.  ) 

Bread  grains 

8.6 

10.8 

3.6 

( 1952-53 ) 

Maize 

14.6 

17.7 

15.4 

(1952-53) 

Potatoes 

4.8 

5.0 

neg 

Cassava 

15.5 

15.9 

neg 

Sugar  ( raw  equivalent ) 

12.2 

12.4 

63 

Bananas 

6.5 

7.5 

79 

Cacao 

0.26 

0.24 

23 

Coffee 

1.85 

1.98 

82 

(1952-53) 

Cotton 

0.79 

1.08 

17 

Hard  fibers 

0.25 

0.24 

22 

Wool  ( clean  basis ) 

0.18 

0.20 

15 

Meat 

5.69 

5.54 

33 

a  United  Nations,  FAO,  The  State  of  Food  and  Agriculture,  19S3,  Part  2   (January,  19S4),  p.  71. 
b  United  Nations,   FAO,   Yearbook  of  Food  and  Agricultural  Statistics,   19S3,  Vol.   7,   Part  2. 


FUTURE  ECONOMIC  PROSPECTS 

Latin  America's  long-term  economic  development  prospects  appear  to 
be  much  more  favorable  than  for  most  other  underdeveloped  regions. 
Except  for  the  lack  of  coal  the  region  has  a  relatively  rich  resource  base 
both  in  agricultural  land  and  minerals.  Although  the  population  is  increas- 
ing rapidly,  the  region  as  a  whole  is  underpopulated,  so  that  greater  num- 
bers should  contribute  to  increasing  returns  in  productive  activities.  More- 
over, the  area  already  has  demonstrated  a  substantial  capacity  for  rapid 
economic  growth  over  the  past  decade  or  more.  In  the  process  many  of 
the  traditional  social  and  institutional  obstacles  to  economic  development 


LATIN  AMERICA  687 

have  been  broken  down.  The  stage  of  Latin  America's  economic  growth 
and  development  has  been  likened  in  many  respects  to  that  of  the  United 
States  during  the  latter  half  of  the  nineteenth  century.23 

Nonetheless,  the  area  faces  many  difficult  economic  problems.  There 
is  the  need  to  maintain  a  proper  balance  between  industrial  development 
and  the  production  of  primary  products.  As  described  above,  a  number 
of  Latin  American  countries  in  their  haste  to  industrialize  have  tended  to 
neglect  the  production  of  agricultural  products  and  minerals.  Since  these 
products  are  the  primary  source  of  export  earnings  needed  to  finance  im- 
ports of  capital  equipment,  the  result  has  frequently  been  to  delay  rather 
than  speed  up  economic  development.  In  some  cases  countries  which 
could  readily  feed  themselves  have  been  sizable  food-deficit  areas.  This 
same  sense  of  urgency  has  commonly  led  governments  to  embark  on 
projects  beyond  their  financial  capabilities.  Frequently  this  has  caused 
widespread  inflation,  thereby  inhibiting  productive  investment  and  creat- 
ing friction  between  employers  and  wage  earners.  Many  uneconomic  in- 
dustries have  been  fostered  by  excessive  protection  and  subsidies.  More 
investment  is  required  in  basic  services  like  transport,  communications, 
and  power.  This  calls  for  a  change  in  the  attitude  of  investors  who  now 
favor  speculative  ventures  with  high  quick  returns.  Managerial  skills  are 
short  in  many  fields.  Most  importantly,  the  level  of  investment  needs  to  be 
raised.  While  savings  and  investment  have  been  relatively  high  in  Latin 
America  as  compared  with  other  underdeveloped  regions,  they  have  been 
inadequate  to  the  task  at  hand.  Raising  the  rate  of  investment  in  the 
absence  of  large  infusions  of  capital  from  abroad  will  be  a  slow  process, 
however,  given  the  present  low  level  of  incomes.  Yet  many  Latin  Amer- 
ican countries,  obsessed  with  fear  of  foreign  exploitation,  pursue  economic 
policies  which  operate  to  keep  out  much  needed  capital  from  abroad. 

For  the  foreseeable  future  it  appears  unlikely,  even  if  the  above  prob- 
lems can  be  met,  that  per  capita  gross  national  product  will  increase  at  a 
faster  rate  than  the  2.5  per  cent  of  the  past  decade  or  so.  This  would  raise 
per  capita  gross  national  product  to  about  $500  in  28  years,  which  is 
within  15  per  cent  of  the  present-day  average  per  capita  gross  national 
product  of  Western  Europe.  With  a  prospective  population  at  that  time 
of  more  than  300  million  people,  Latin  America  could  thus  be  an  area  of 
considerable  economic  capabilities. 

Clearly  the  extent  and  the  pattern  of  Latin  America's  economic  de- 
velopment is  likely  to  vary  widely  from  country  to  country.  Certain  Cen- 

23  Foreign  Operation  Administration,  Report  on  The  Economic  Situation  in  Latin 
America  (Washington,  D.  C,  August,  1954),  p.  5. 


688       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

tral  American  countries  and  most  of  the  West  Indies  with  their  limited 
resources  and  dense  populations  are  likely  to  advance  less  rapidly  than 
the  average.  The  rich  agricultural  resources  of  the  southern  republics  of 
Latin  America,  and  their  lack  of  iron  ore  and  coal,  suggests  that  this 
area  will  not  achieve  the  degree  of  industrial  specialization  of  Western 
Europe.24  Tropical  Latin  America,  particularly  Brazil  and  Venezuela,  also 
lacking  in  coal,  has  vast  iron  ore  reserves  and  a  tremendous  water  power 
potential.  Its  resource  base,  therefore,  offers  greater  possibilities  for  the 
development  of  industry  than  the  rest  of  the  region.  Climatic  factors,  lack 
of  skilled  labor,  and  the  high  cost  of  capital,  however,  may  well  delay  this 
development  until  some  time  in  the  more  distant  future.  In  the  meantime 
tropical  agriculture  and  mining  are  likely  to  be  of  continuing  importance. 

24  A.  J.  Brown,  Industrialization  and  Trade,  pamphlet  published  by  The  Royal 
Institute  of  International  Affairs  (London,  September,  1943),  p.  23. 


CHAPTER 


23 


Arrica:   The  Last  Stand  or 
Colonialism 


Africa  is  the  last  of  the  large  colonial  areas,  with  roughly  70  per  cent  of 
its  territory  under  some  form  of  foreign  control.  However,  this  vast  con- 
tinent is  showing  increasing  signs  of  restiveness  under  foreign  tutelage. 
"Africa  is  headed  for  great  political  changes.  The  trend  of  events  is  inexor- 
ably toward  an  adjustment  in  relations  between  the  native  population 
and  its  European  rulers."  x  Violent  disorders  already  have  broken  out 
since  World  War  II  in  a  number  of  territories,  particularly  in  French 
North  Africa  and  British  East  Africa.  Growing  local  disturbances  in 
Algeria  have  developed  because  of  dissatisfaction  with  the  speed  of 
French  political  and  economic  reforms.  In  British  East  Africa,  resort 
to  violence  is  largely  a  result  of  native  frustration  over  policies  of  white 
supremacy.  So  far,  Belgian  and  French  colonies  south  of  the  Sahara 
have  been  spared  these  difficulties  as  a  result  of  their  paternalistic  eco- 
nomic policies  and  the  absence  of  color  discrimination.  In  some  areas 
local  aspirations  for  greater  freedom  have  been  met  by  substantial 
political  concessions,  as  in  the  Gold  Coast,  Nigeria,  and  the  Anglo-Egyp- 
tian Sudan.  Whether  the  necessary  concessions  will  be  made  elsewhere  in 
time  to  avoid  widespread  political  and  social  disturbances  remains  to  be 
seen.  Such  a  development  clearly  would  be  damaging  to  the  strength  of 
the  Free  World  because  of  the  importance  of  a  politically  stable  and 
friendly  Africa  as  a  source  of  many  strategic  materials,  as  a  safeguard  to 

1  C.  W.  de  Kiewiet,  "African  Dilemmas,"  Foreign  Affairs  (April,  1955),  pp.  444-457. 

689 


3 

4 


7 

A  * 

n 

12 
14 

■ 
■ 

J 

* 

♦  ♦ 

S 

r 

10 

'/ 

**  v  *  *   *  ' 

Fig.  23-1.  Resources,  Railroads  and  Political  Structure  of  Africa:  (1)  independent;  (2)  British 
colonies;  (3)  Belgium  colonies;  (4)  French  colonies;  (5)  Portuguese  colonies;  (6)  Italian 
mandate;  (7)  tin;  (8)  lead  and  zinc;  (9)  phosphate;  (10)  petroleum;  (11)  gold;  (12) 
diamonds;  (13)  aluminum;  (14)  iron  ore;  (15)  copper;  (16)  coal;  (17)  railroads;  (18) 
proposed  railroads. 


690 


AFRICA:  THE  LAST  STAND  OF  COLONIALISM  691 

the  security  of  Allied  naval  and  air  bases  on  the  continent,  and  as  a  pro- 
tection for  key  lines  of  communication  in  time  of  war. 

AREA  AND  POPULATION 

Africa,  with  an  area  of  11.7  million  square  miles,  is  exceeded  in  size  only 
by  Asia  (including  Asiatic  U.S.S.R. ).  Its  distance  north  to  south  is  5,000 
miles  and  its  maximum  breadth  is  4,600  miles.  Although  Africa  embraces 
more  than  20  per  cent  of  the  surface  of  the  earth,  its  estimated  population 
of  212  million  (1953)  is  less  than  9  per  cent  of  the  world  total.  Average 
population  density  is  slightly  more  than  18  persons  per  square  mile.  Only 
Oceania  among  the  continental  areas  is  more  thinly  populated.  The 
sparseness  of  Africa's  population  has  been  a  serious  hindrance  to  the  area's 
economic  growth,  leading  to  the  prevailing  wasteful  system  of  migrant 
labor,  limiting  the  development  of  the  domestic  market,  and  frustrating 
the  construction  of  an  economic  transport  and  communications  system. 

Only  six  countries  in  Africa  (Figure  23-1)— Egypt,  the  Sudan,  Ethiopia, 
Liberia,  Libya,  and  the  Union  of  South  Africa— are  politically  independent. 
These  account  for  approximately  26  per  cent  of  the  continent's  total  area 
and  29  per  cent  of  its  population.  Tunisia,  Morocco  and  the  Gold  Coast 
are  scheduled  to  become  completely  independent  in  1956  or  1957.  The 
rest  of  Africa  consists  of  non-self-governing  territories  and  dependencies 
in  varying  stages  of  transition  toward  self-government  which,  except  for 
South-West  Africa  are  under  the  jurisdiction  of  European  countries.  South- 
West  Africa,  a  former  mandated  territory,  is  controlled  by  the  Union  of 
South  Africa.  The  percentages  of  African  territory  controlled  by  European 
metropoles  are  roughly  as  follows: 


PERCENTAGE 

COUNTRY 

OF  ALL  AFRICA 

France 

37a 

United  Kingdom 

28b 

Relgium 

8 

Portugal 

7 

Italy 

2 

Spain 

1 

"  Including  Tunisia  and  Morocco. 
b  Including  the  Gold  Coast. 


The  borders  separating  individual  African  territories  are  almost  wholly 
artificial  in  the  sense  that  they  show  little  or  no  relationship  to  ethnic  or 
geographic  factors.  Boundaries  cut  through  tribes  and  separate  natural 
geographic  regions.  The  extent  and  configuration  of  most  African  terri- 


S92        THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

tories  largely  reflect  the  success  of  the  respective  European  metropoles  in 
carving  out  their  claims.  As  one  writer  has  aptly  pointed  out,  African 
"boundaries  of  territories  were,  and  are,  no  more  than  the  result  of  con- 
ference and  negotiation  by  statesmen  in  Europe,  by  whom,  40  and  50 
years  ago,  African  human  geography  was  unknown  and  economics  little 
understood.  Frontiers  were  drawn  with  a  ruler  on  a  blank  map,  or  by  give 
and  take  about  the  unknown,  in  Western  foreign  ministries  .  . ."  2 

Despite  its  predominantly  colonial  status,  Africa  has  been  of  minor 
importance  as  an  outlet  for  European  immigration.  Climate  and  closely 
related  health  problems  have  been  the  main  obstacles  to  European  settle- 
ment, but  modern  technology  and  new  developments  in  public  health 
could  overcome  these  drawbacks.  Persons  of  European  descent  living  in 
Africa  number  only  about  5.5  million,  or  less  than  3  per  cent  of  the  total 
population.  Most  of  these  live  in  the  more  temperate  and  disease-free 
regions  of  the  continent.  Approximately  3  million  are  to  be  found  in  the 
Union  of  South  Africa,  less  than  2  million  in  Mediterranean  Africa.  The 
balance  is  located  chiefly  in  East  and  Central  Africa,  attracted  by  the 
relatively  favorable  climate  and  the  presence  of  considerable  mineral 
wealth.  In  addition,  Africa  south  of  the  Sahara  has  an  important  non- 
African  minority  of  Syrians,  Lebanese,  and  Indians  and  Pakistani.  This 
group  is  engaged  largely  in  commerce  and  is  a  target  of  considerable 
native  antipathy. 

Population  density  varies  widely  from  country  to  country  (see  Table 
23-1 )  and  is  strongly  influenced  by  geographic  factors.  In  interpreting  the 
low  average  densities  it  must  be  recognized  that  many  parts  of  Africa  are 
virtually  uninhabitable.  Thus  Egypt  is  more  than  95  per  cent  desert  and 
in  terms  of  productive  land  has  a  density  in  excess  of  2,000  per  square 
mile.  However,  few  areas  of  Africa  are  overpopulated  in  the  sense  that 
there  is  a  continuous  supply  of  surplus  labor.  Except  for  Egypt  and 
mining  centers  in  Southern  and  South-Central  Africa,  there  is  a  close 
correlation  between  population  and  mean  average  rainfall.3  Tropical 
Africa  shows  much  greater  population  density  than  comparable  areas  of 
South  America.  Gourou  suggests  that  differences  in  the  accessibility  of 
the  two  continents  may  account  for  these  variations;  the  greater  naviga- 
bility of  the  Amazon  as  compared  with  the  Congo  made  it  easier  for 
Europeans  to  penetrate  the  Amazon  valley  and  to  inflict  damage  on  the 
native  population  by  spreading  disease,  by  slave  hunts,  and  by  instituting 

2  C.  G.  Haines  (ed.),  Africa  Today  (Baltimore,  1955),  p.  20. 

3  W.  Fitzgerald,  Africa,  4th  ed.  (New  York,  1942),  p.  108. 


AFRICA:  THE  LAST  STAND  OF  COLONIALISM 


89J 


serfdom.4  Unlike  Latin  America,  Africa  has  few  urban  concentrations  of 
population. 

TABLE  23-1 
Africa:   Area,  Population  and  Population  Density  of  Principal  Countries 


POPULATION 

area" 

POPULATION 

1953 b 

COUNTRY 

(000  so.  mi.) 

(000) 

DENSITY 

(per  sq.  mi.) 

Algeria 

846.1 

9,367 

11.0 

Sudan 

967.5 

8,820 

9.1 

Belgian  Congo 

905.0 

12,154 

13.4 

Egypt 

386.0 

21,935 

57.0 

Ethiopia 

409.3 

15,000  (1951) 

36.7 

French  Equatorial  Africa 

969.1 

4,492 

(1952) 

4.6 

French  West  Africa 

1,835.0 

17,435  (1952) 

9.5 

Gold  Coast 

78.8 

4,062 

51.5 

Kenya 

225.0 

5,851 

26.0 

Liberia 

43.0 

1,648 

(1949) 

38.3 

Libya 

706.6 

1,500 

21.2 

Madagascar 

227.7 

4,464 

19.6 

Morocco 

150.2 

8,220 

54.7 

Mozambique 

297.7 

5,895 

19.8 

Nigeria 

338.6 

30,000 

88.6 

Northern  Rhodesia 

290.3 

2,020 

6.9 

Southern  Rhodesia 

150,3 

2,260 

15.0 

Tanganyika 

362.4 

8,069 

22.3 

Tunisia 

60.2 

3,630 

60.3 

Uganda 

94.0 

5,343 

56.9 

Union  of  South  Africa 

472.7 

13,153 

27.8 

Other 

1,880.6 

27,379 

14.5 

Total 

11,696 

212,697 

Av.  18.2 

a  United  Nations,  Statistical   Yearbook,   19S2. 

b  United  Nations,  Population  and  Vital  Statistics  Reports  (New  York,  October,   1954). 

Three  distinct  demographic  regions  may  be  identified  in  Africa.  North- 
ern or  Mediterranean  Africa  is  characterized  by  high  birth  rates  and 
declining  though  still  high  death  rates.  Recent  rates  of  population  in- 
crease in  this  region  have  been  estimated  by  the  United  Nations  at  1.56 
per  cent  per  annum  and  may  reach  a  "medium"  rate  of  1.86  per  cent  by 
1980  as  death  rates  continue  to  fall.5  Middle  or  intertropical  Africa  is 
characterized  by  both  high  birth  and  death  rates.  Satisfactory  estimates 
of  population  growth  in  this  area  are  limited  by  the  poverty  of  informa- 
tion. The  United  Nations  considers  one  per  cent  as  a  "medium"  figure  for 
the  present  rate  of  population  growth,  with  an  upper  limit  of  1.5  per  cent 
and  a  lower  limit  of  0.5  per  cent.  In  the  absence  of  more  definite  mortality 

4  P.  Gourou,  The  Tropical  World  (London,  1952),  p.  125. 

5  United  Nations,  Framework  For  Future  Population  Estimates,  1950-1980,  By 
Regions  (1954). 


694       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

trends,  it  was  estimated  that  growth  rates  over  the  next  twenty-five  years 
in  this  area  would  continue  about  as  at  present.  The  third  demographic 
area  is  Southern  Africa,  with  high  birth  rates  and  fairly  low  death  rates. 
Here  the  current  rate  of  population  increase  is  estimated  at  2.15  per  cent 
per  annum  with  a  projected  "medium"  rate  of  2.32  per  cent  by  1980.  The 
total  population  of  Africa  is  projected  at  roughly  300  million  by  1980. 

GEOGRAPHY  AND  CLIMATE 

Geographic  factors  probably  have  had  a  more  significant  effect  on 
Africa's  general  development  than  on  that  of  any  other  continent.  The 
continent's  forbidding  physical  characteristics  go  a  long  way  toward 
explaining  the  late  opening  up  of  the  area  south  of  the  Mediterranean 
littoral.6  The  hot  humid  interior  is  infested  with  virulent  tropical  diseases. 
The  coast  has  few  good  harbors  and  the  rivers  do  not  provide  easy  access 
to  the  interior  because  of  water  falls  and  rapids  near  the  coast.  Only  the 
Congo  has  a  deep  water  estuary.  Extremely  rugged  topography  impedes 
travel  north  and  south.  It  is  not  surprising,  therefore,  that  Africa's  real 
contact  with  the  outside  world,  except  in  the  climatically  more  favorable 
extreme  north  and  south,  did  not  begin  until  the  closing  decades  of  the 
nineteenth  century. 

Africa  is  the  most  tropical  of  all  continents,  with  almost  four-fifths  of 
its  total  area  lying  in  the  tropics.  It  is  bisected  by  the  equator  and  has 
roughly  the  same  climate  zones  in  the  north  and  south.  Most  of  Africa 
is  a  plateau  with  elevations  of  from  1,000  to  4,000  feet,  flanked  by  moun- 
tain chains  in  the  extreme  northwest  and  on  the  southern  margins  of  the 
Cape.  Elevations  are  highest  south  of  the  equator,  particularly  in  the  east, 
making  for  more  temperate  climatic  conditions  than  in  the  north.  The 
plateau's  edge  is  close  to  the  seaboard  so  that  Africa  has  very  narrow 
coastal  plains.  The  shore  line  lacks  indentations  and  except  in  the  Medi- 
terranean there  are  few  natural  harbors.  Ocean  depths  descend  abruptly 
save  off  the  Mediterranean  and  extreme  southern  coasts.  As  a  result  there 
is  a  lack  of  feeding  grounds  for  fish,  and  fishing  plays  a  negligible  role  in 
the  life  of  the  people. 

Four  major  climate  zones  may  be  distinguished.  The  first  is  the  area 
approximately  5  degrees  north  and  5  degrees  south  of  the  equator  which 
is  hot,  humid,  and  has  rain  throughout  the  year.  This  region,  which 
extends  for  a  distance  of  400  miles  on  each  side  of  the  equator,  is  covered 
by  a  dense  tropical  rain  forest.  The  next  zone,  extending  roughly  from  5 

6  Lord,  Hailey,  An  African  Survey,  2nd  ed.  (New  York,  1945). 


AFRICA:  THE  LAST  STAND  OF  COLONIALISM  695 

degrees  to  15  degrees  north  and  south  of  the  equator,  is  also  hot  and 
humid  but  receives  all  of  its  precipitation  in  the  summer.  This  area,  which 
is  600  to  800  miles  wide  on  each  side  of  the  Equatorial  Zone,  is  the  tropi- 
cal grassland  or  park-savanna  region.  The  vegetation  consists  primarily 
of  scrub  forest  and  coarse  grass  5  to  12  feet  high.  Ocean  currents  and 
mountains  modify  the  characteristic  climate  of  these  two  zones.  Kenya, 
Tankanyika,  Uganda,  Nyasaland,  and  Mozambique  in  East  Africa  have 
quite  equable  climates  except  in  the  low-lying  coastal  regions.  Elevations 
of  more  than  4,000  feet  produce  climates  not  unlike  the  Andean  plateau 
of  Colombia.  At  Nairobi,  which  is  almost  on  the  equator  but  has  an  ele- 
vation of  5,500  feet,  the  highest  average  monthly  temperature  is  66  de- 
grees and  the  lowest  58  degrees.  These  are  the  only  regions  in  tropical 
Africa  which  have  attracted  European  settlers  in  any  numbers,  giving 
rise  to  serious  conflicts  of  interest  between  the  whites  and  the  natives. 

The  third  zone  is  the  hot  desert  which  extends  between  15  degrees  and  30 
degrees  north  and  south  of  the  equator.  Temperatures  are  high  through- 
out the  year  and  there  is  virtually  no  precipitation.  North  of  the  equator 
this  zone  includes  the  Sahara  desert  which  extends  from  the  Atlantic 
Coast  to  the  Red  Sea  and  has  an  average  width  of  800  miles.  The  Sahara 
has  an  area  almost  equal  that  of  the  United  States  and  except  for  occa- 
sional oases  is  only  suitable  for  nomadic  herdsmen.  The  Sahara  has  been 
a  major  barrier  to  the  spread  of  ancient  Mediterranean  cultures  to  the 
south,  and  has  been  an  important  factor  in  Middle  Africa's  backwardness. 
South  of  the  equator,  desert  conditions  are  repeated  only  in  South-West 
Africa.  The  southeast  trade  winds  bring  rain,  precipitated  by  the  South 
African  plateau,  to  the  eastern  part  of  the  subcontinent. 

The  fourth  zone  covers  the  area  beyond  30  degrees  north  and  south  of 
the  equator  and  includes  the  Mediterranean  littoral  of  Morocco,  Algeria, 
and  Tunisia  in  the  north  and  the  southwestern  corner  of  the  Union  of 
South  Africa.  Here  the  climate  is  typically  Mediterranean,  not  African, 
with  mild  rainy  winters  and  hot  dry  summers.  The  Atlas  range  in  the 
northwest  precipitates  moisture  from  winds  blowing  from  Europe  and  the 
Atlantic,  thereby  making  the  land  between  the  mountains  and  the  sea 
habitable.  East  of  Tunisia,  in  the  absence  of  such  mountains,  the  sea  and 
the  desert  come  together  for  most  of  the  800  miles  of  Libya's  coastline. 
Here  again  the  desert  has  presented  a  significant  obstacle  to  direct  cul- 
tural exchange  between  Egypt  and  the  French  North  African  littoral.  As 
pointed  out  in  the  United  Nations  World  Economic  Report  1949-50, 
"North  Africa,  bordering  on  the  Mediterranean,  and  separated  from  the 
rest  of  Africa  by  the  vast  wastes  of  the  Sahara  desert,  is  by  history  and 


696        THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

geography  closely  associated  with  southern  Europe,  of  which  in  an  eco- 
nomic sense  much  of  it  forms  an  integral  part."  Although  a  part  of  Africa 
geographically,  South  Africa  is  cut  off  from  the  rest  of  the  continent  by 
the  formidable  barriers  of  the  Karoo  desert  and  the  southern  mountain 
ranges. 

RESOURCES 

Widely  divergent  views  prevail  as  to  Africa's  economic  potential.  In 
part  at  least  these  differences  stem  from  the  fact  that  the  area's  resources 
have  been  only  partially  assessed.  On  the  basis  of  presently  available 
information  it  would  appear  that  Africa  is  by  no  means  "a  promised  land." 
Like  most  predominantly  tropical  regions,  Africa's  resource  base  is  seri- 
ously deficient  in  many  important  respects.  Soils  are  much  poorer  in 
essential  minerals  and  humus  than  in  temperate  regions.  They  erode 
rapidly  and  decline  in  fertility  under  constant  cropping.  Desert  and  poor 
scrub  land  cover  nearly  one-third  of  the  continent  and  the  desert  is  slowly 
spreading  south.  Africa  is  less  healthy  than  regions  in  the  temperate  belt. 
Much  of  Africa's  vast  tropical  forest  area  contains  species  of  little  or  no 
worth.  Although  a  major  world  source  of  many  important  minerals  such 
as  copper,  gold,  manganese,  and  uranium,  Africa  is  deficient  in  coal,  iron 
ore,  and  petroleum.  It  does,  however,  have  a  vast  untapped  water  power 
potential,  which  has  given  rise  to  a  number  of  ambitious  plans  for  hydro- 
electric power  development.  One  of  these,  which  the  Central  African 
Federation  has  decided  to  undertake,  would  involve  the  damming  of  the 
Zambesi  River  at  Kariba  gorge  and  would  be  larger  than  Boulder  Dam. 
Cheap  power  and  industrialization  offer  one  solution  of  the  pressure  of 
the  increasing  native  population  on  the  land. 

Agricultural  Land.  According  to  statistics  compiled  by  the  Food  and 
Agriculture  Organization,  Africa,  with  approximately  7  per  cent  of  its 
total  area  classified  as  arable  land,  has  the  lowest  ratio  of  cultivable  land 
of  all  continental  regions  except  Oceania.  Nonetheless  arable  land  (in- 
cluding fallow  and  orchards )  in  relation  to  population  appears  to  be  con- 
siderable, averaging  2.8  acres  per  capita  for  the  continent  as  a  whole  ( see 
Table  23-2 ) .  There  are  of  course  a  number  of  countries  with  substantially 
less  than  this  average,  the  most  outstanding  being  Egypt  with  less  than 
one-third  of  an  acre  per  capita.  The  population  is  also  pressing  on  the 
land  in  French  North  Africa  and  Kenya.  The  high  average  figure  is  gen- 
erally misleading  on  other  grounds.  Water  supply  is  inadequate  or  unre- 
liable in  many  areas.  Furthermore,  a  considerable  proportion  of  the  arable 
land  continually  lies  fallow  in  tropical  Africa.  Since  tropical  soils  rapidly 


AFRICA:  THE  LAST  STAND  OF  COLONIALISM 


697 


lose  their  fertility  under  constant  cropping,  shifting  cultivation  as  in  the 
uplands  of  Southeast  Asia  is  the  traditional  method  of  native  farming.  A 
piece  of  ground  will  be  planted  for  only  a  few  years,  and  as  its  fertility  is 
exhausted  it  will  be  abandoned  and  permitted  to  relapse  into  forest  or 
savanna.  After  the  lapse  of  a  certain  number  of  years  the  fertility  of  the 
exhausted  land  is  at  least  partly  restored  and  it  is  cleared  and  used  again. 

TABLE  23-2 
Africa:  Arable  and  Potentially  Productive  Land  in  Selected  Areas  * 


COUNTRY 

PERIOD 

TOTAL  ARABLE 

LAND    (iNCL. 

FALLOW  AND 

ORCHARDS  ) 

( 000  ACRES ) 

ARABLE  LAND 
PER  CAPITA 

(1953 

POPULATION  ) 

total  unused 

but  potentially 

productive 

(000  acres) 

Algeria 

1951 

15,686 

1.7 

Sudan 

1951 

5,888 

0.7 

Belgian  Congo 

1951 

121,079 

10.0 

Egypt 

1951 

6,056 

0.3 

1,633 

Ethiopia 

1951 

27,181 

1.8 

19,768 

French  Equatorial  Africa 

1950 

74,130 

16.5 

French  West  Africa 

1950 

24,710 

1.4 

Gold  Coast 

1951 

13,121 

3.2 

Kenya 

1948 

3,954 

0.7 

Liberia 

1948 

4.480 

2.7 

6,721 

Madagascar 

1947 

12,355 

2.8 

618 

Morocco 

1950 

19,609 

2.4 

18,557" 

Mozambique 

1948 

4,942 

0.8 

Southern  Bhodesia 

1951 

3,825 

1.7 

Tanganyika 

1948 

7,413 

0.9 

Tunisia 

1951 

9,496 

2.6 

Union  of  South  Africa 

1951 

19,028 
600,453 

1.4 

ALL  AFRICA 

Av.  2.8 

a  Includes  rough   grazings. 

*  United   Nations,    Food    and   Agriculture    Organization,    Yearbook    of   Food   and   Agricultural   Statistics, 
19S2,  Vol.   6,   Part   1. 

This  shifting  system  of  agriculture  requires  many  more  acres  to  support 
a  family  than  under  a  permanent  system  where  a  single  plot  can  be  culti- 
vated continuously.  According  to  Stamp,  the  practice  of  shifting  cultiva- 
tion in  Nigeria  should  allow  seven  years  of  fallow  for  each  year  of 
cultivation.  This  would  mean  that  the  average  family  of  3.6  persons  cul- 
tivating an  average  plot  of  2  acres  needs  16  acres  of  land  to  support  itself.7 
A  few  countries  like  Ethiopia  have  rich  and  fairly  accessible  lands  avail- 
able for  exploitation.  In  general,  however,  under  existing  agricultural 
techniques  arable  land  per  capita  in  Africa  is  not  plentiful.  On  the  con- 

7  L.  D.  Stamp,  "Land  Utilization  and  Soil  Erosion  in  Nigeria,"  Geographical  Re- 
view (1938),  p.  35. 


698       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

trary,  with  the  expansion  of  population  the  supply  of  arable  land  over 
much  of  the  continent  is  becoming  increasingly  inadequate,  and  many 
areas  are  experiencing  growing  difficulties  in  satisfying  their  food  require- 
ments. A  considerable  area  of  Africa  is  more  suitable  for  pastoral  than  for 
crop-raising  pursuits.  However,  large  regions  in  the  park-savanna  country 
are  infested  with  the  tsetse-fly  and  cannot  be  used  for  livestock  raising 
until  immunization  against  sleeping  sickness  is  developed.  Then  Africa 
south  of  the  Sahara  could  become  one  of  the  major  grazing  areas  of  the 
world.8 

Forest  Resources.  Forests  cover  25  per  cent  of  the  total  area  of  Africa 
and  exceed  those  of  Latin  America  in  extent.  However,  Africa  does  not 
compare  with  Latin  America  as  a  storehouse  of  tropical  timber  since  only 
40  per  cent  of  the  forest  area  is  productive  forest.  Moreover,  of  this  pro- 
ductive share  roughly  60  per  cent  is  inaccessible.9  Until  very  recently  the 
continent  traditionally  was  a  deficit  area  in  forestry  and  forest  products. 
Almost  all  African  forests  are  of  hardwood  varieties  and  commercial  out- 
lets have  been  found  for  only  a  limited  number  of  species.  In  1948  Africa 
produced  only  between  one  and  two  per  cent  of  the  Free  World's  output 
of  industrial  wood.  It  has  been  estimated  that  production  will  barely  keep 
pace  with  growing  requirements  over  the  next  two  or  three  decades. 

Minerals.  Although  Africa  has  a  number  of  serious  mineral  deficiencies 
her  mineral  resources  in  many  categories  are  equal  or  superior  to  those 
of  any  other  continent  (cf.  Fig.  23-1).  The  presence  of  these  minerals 
has  been  a  major  incentive  to  European  intervention  in  Africa  and 
has  significantly  affected  relationships  between  the  native  populations  and 
Europeans.  Africa  leads  the  world  in  reserves  of  copper,  cobalt,  chromite, 
manganese,  uranium,  industrial  and  gem  quality  diamonds,  and  phosphate 
rock  (see  Table  23-3).  Reserves  of  bauxite,  antimony,  tin,  asbestos,  and 
rare  metals  such  as  columbium,  tantalum  and  platinum  are  more  than  ade- 
quate. While  not  in  the  strategic-metal  category,  Africa's  gold  fields  are 
the  richest  in  the  world  and  have  played  a  vital  role  in  financing  South 
Africa's  economic  development.  The  richest  mineral  regions  are  the 
Union  of  South  Africa,  South- West  Africa,  Southern  and  Northern  Rhode- 
sia, and  the  Belgian  Congo. 

Of  the  non-ferrous  metals  the  two  principal  deficiencies  are  lead  and 
zinc.  More  significant,  however,  are  the  lack  of  mineral  fuels  and  iron  ore. 
Africa  depends  on  external  sources  for  about  one-sixth  of  its  energy  sup- 

8  F.  Osborn,  The  Limits  of  the  Earth  (London,  1954),  p.  85. 

9  The  President's  Materials  Policy  Commission,  Resources  For  Freedom,  Vol.  5 
(Washington,  D.  C,  June,  1952),  p.  55. 


AFRICA:  THE  LAST  STAND  OF  COLONIALISM  699 

plies.10  Egypt  has  the  only  productive  oil  resources  and  these  represent 
less  than  a  fraction  of  one  per  cent  of  total  world  reserves.  Africa  has  the 
smallest  coal  reserves  of  any  continent.  Proved  reserves  of  coal  in  Africa 
have  been  estimated  at  2  per  cent  of  the  world  total  and  probable  reserves 
at  4  per  cent.11  The  bulk  of  these  reserves  are  in  the  Union  of  South 
Africa  and  Rhodesia.  Most  of  the  known  deposits  are  of  poor  quality  and 
occurrences  of  coking  coal  are  few.  In  contrast  with  its  limited  coal  re- 
serves Africa  is  estimated  to  have  40  per  cent  of  the  world's  water  power 
resources,  or  four  times  the  potential  of  North  America.  Lack  of  fuel  re- 
sources will  be  a  handicap  to  industrialization  in  many  parts  of  Africa  in 
the  absence  of  large-scale  electrification.  Africa's  iron  ore  reserves  amount 
to  somewhat  less  than  15  per  cent  of  the  world  total  and  most  of  these 
have  less  than  50  per  cent  iron  content.  These  iron  ore  reserves  are  found 
chiefly  in  the  Union  of  South  Africa,  in  Southern  Rhodesia,  and  in  French 
West  Africa.  On  the  basis  of  the  presently  known  occurrences  of  coal  and 
iron  ore,  only  the  Union  of  South  Africa  and  Southern  Rhodesia  have  the 
raw  material  resources  necessary  to  support  a  significant  iron  and  steel 
industry. 

TABLE  23-3 
Africa:  Reserves  of  Selected  Minerals  as  Percentage  of  Free  World  Total  * 

MINERAL  PER  CENT  PRINCIPAL  PRODUCING  AREAS 

Copper  40  Belgian  Congo  and  Northern  Rhodesia 

Manganese  (av.  grade  45%)  38  Union  of  South  Africa,  Belgian  Congo, 

Morocco 
Manganese   (av.  grade  25%)  20  Morocco,  Belgian  Congo 

Chromite  80  Union    of    South    Africa    and    Southern 

Rhodesia 
Phosphate  rock  70  French  North  Africa 

Diamonds  95  Belgian    Congo    and    Union    of    South 

Africa 
Cobalt  90  Belgian  Congo,  Northern  Rhodesia 

Lead  6  Morocco,  Nigeria 

Zinc  5  Belgian  Congo,  Morocco 

*  The  President's   Materials  Policy   Commission,  Resources  For  Freedom,  Vol.   2    (Washington,   D.   C). 


ECONOMIC  AND  STRATEGIC  IMPORTANCE 

Africa's  over-all  international  economic  importance  is  not  proportion- 
ate to  its  population  and  area.  In  1953,  Africa  accounted  for  less  than  7 
per  cent  of  world  trade.  Nonetheless  the  continent  was  a  very  important 

10  United  Nations,  Review  of  Economic  Conditions  in  Africa  (New  York,  February-, 
1951),  p.  106. 

11  Ibid.,  p.  107. 


700       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

if  not  a  major  factor  in  the  foreign  trade  of  a  number  of  European  colo- 
nial powers.  In  1953,  France,  Portugal,  the  United  Kingdom,  and  Bel- 
gium-Luxembourg conducted  30  per  cent,  25  per  cent,  15  per  cent,  and 
10  per  cent  respectively  of  their  total  foreign  trade  with  Africa.  Most  of 
this  was  with  their  colonies.  The  largest  share  of  the  foreign  trade  of  the 
African  dependencies  is  engrossed  by  the  European  metropoles.  In  1953, 
the  share  of  the  foreign  trade  of  the  dependent  territories  with  their 
respective  mother  countries  was  as  follows :  1 2 


SHARE  OF  EXPORTS 

SHARE  OF  IMPORTS 

DEPENDENCY 

TO  METROPOLE 

FROM  METROPOLE 

British  1 

53 

47 

French  2 

63 

67 

Belgian 

56 

40 

Portuguese 

24 

40 

Includes  Gold  Coast. 

2  Includes  Tunisia  and  Morocco. 

The  economic  importance  of  the  dependencies  to  the  metropoles  is  of 
course  not  limited  to  trade.  A  significant  share  of  the  overseas  invest- 
ments of  France,  the  United  Kingdom,  and  Belgium  have  been  made  in 
Africa.  These  investments  are  highly  productive  and  profitable,  are  impor- 
tant earners  of  foreign  exchange,  and  provide  the  metropoles  with  essen- 
tial foodstuffs  and  industrial  raw  materials.  Estimates  of  the  United  States 
Department  of  Commerce  place  total  book  value  of  American  direct  in- 
vestments in  Africa,  exclusive  of  Egypt,  at  $458  million  at  the  end  of  1952. 

Africa  is  a  major  producer  of  a  large  number  of  industrial  raw  mate- 
rials and  foodstuffs,  chiefly  for  export.  The  most  important  of  these  are 
listed  in  Table  23-4.  Not  included  is  uranium,  for  which  no  production 
figures  are  available  because  of  security  reasons.  However,  Africa— prin- 
cipally the  Belgian  Congo  and  the  Union  of  South  Africa— is  believed  to 
be  the  world's  largest  producer.  The  Union  of  South  Africa  produces 
more  than  half  of  the  Free  World's  output  of  gold.  Most  of  this  gold  is 
shipped  to  the  United  Kingdom  and  makes  an  important  contribution  to 
meeting  the  sterling  area's  hard-currency  needs. 

Brief  mention  needs  to  be  made  of  North  Africa's  locational  impor- 
tance by  virtue  of  its  position  astride  the  vital  Mediterranean  and  Suez 
passageway  to  the  Indian  Ocean  and  the  Far  East.  As  mentioned  in 
Chapter  19  this  route  is  of  great  commercial  and  strategic  significance 
to  the  Free  World  and  in  particular  to  the  United  Kingdom  and  the  Far 
East.  "Because  of  its  geographical  relationship  to  the  highways  of  the 

12  Compiled  from  United  Nations,  Direction  of  International  Trade,  Series  T,  Vol. 
5,  No.  8  (New  York). 


AFRICA:  THE  LAST  STAND  OF  COLONIALISM  701 

Mediterranean,  to  the  Atlantic  and  the  Indian  Oceans,  and  to  the  oil  fields 
of  the  Middle  East,  Africa  would  immediately  become  part  of  the  global 
front  line  in  the  event  of  war."  13  The  experience  of  the  past  war  demon- 
strated the  great  strategic  importance  of  North  Africa  as  a  logistical 
springboard  in  any  military  operations  against  southern  Europe.  The  area 
has  a  string  of  airbases  which  form  a  vital  part  of  the  Free  World's  first 
line  of  defense  against  Soviet  aggression.  North  Africa's  strategic  impor- 
tance is  enhanced  by  virtue  of  its  highly  defensible  position  between  the 
desert  and  the  sea. 

TABLE  23-4 
Africa:   Share  of  Free  World  Output  of  Selected  Raw  Materials,  1950 


MINERAL 

PER  CENT 

AGRICULTURAL       . 

PER  CENT 

Manganese  (ore) 

54 

Groundnuts 

20 

Copper  (metal) 

24 

Coffee 

13 

Antimony  (metal) 

25 

Cocoa 

66 

Cobalt  (metal) 

87 

Cotton 

13 

Tin  (metal) 

19 

Sisal8 

50 

Industrial  diamonds 

87 

Palm   oil" 

69 

Chrome  (ore) 

45 

> 

Asbestos 

12 

Graphite 

10 

Phosphate  rock 

35 

*  Per  cent  of  world  exports. 

GENERAL  ECONOMIC  DEVELOPMENT 

Africa  is  the  most  backward  of  the  major  underdeveloped  regions.  With 
more  than  8  per  cent  of  the  world's  population,  it  accounts  for  only  about 
2.5  per  cent  of  the  world's  production.  All  of  this  vast  continent  with  the 
exception  of  the  Union  of  South  Africa  falls  into  the  underdeveloped 
category.  Nonetheless,  significant  regional  variations  are  to  be  found  in 
the  pattern  and  degree  of  economic  development.  Broadly  speaking,  three 
major  zones  of  economic  development  can  be  identified.  The  first  is 
North  Africa,  which  embraces  the  Mediterranean  countries  from  Morocco 
in  the  west  to  Egypt  in  the  east  and  has  a  population  of  roughly  40  mil- 
lion. As  pointed  out  elsewhere,  this  area  except  for  Egypt  is  really  an 
extension  of  the  European  Mediterranean  economy.  As  a  result  of  its 
longer  exposure  to  European  influences,  North  Africa  is  generally  more 
advanced  than  the  rest  of  Africa.  The  second  and  by  far  the  largest  eco- 
nomic region  is  Middle  or  Intertropical  Africa,  which  extends  roughly 

13  de  Kiewiet,  op.  cit.,  p.  447. 


702       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

from  30  degrees  north  latitude  to  the  Union  of  South  Africa.  This  area 
with  a  population  of  140  million  is  only  beginning  to  emerge  from  almost 
complete  dependence  on  subsistence  pursuits  to  participation  in  various 
forms  of  activities  involving  money  exchange.  According  to  Albion  Ross 
in  his  series  of  articles  on  Africa,  published  in  The  New  York  Times, 
middle  Africa  "is  filled  with  people  still  in  the  childhood  stage  of  the 
human  race  . .  ."  14  Finally,  there  is  the  Union  of  South  Africa  which,  at 
least  in  the  European  sector,  has  most  of  the  characteristics  of  a  highly 
developed  western  economy. 

Poverty  and  disease  are  endemic  in  Africa.  Food  shortage  is  widespread 
and  much  of  the  population  is  undernourished  and  too  weak  to  resist 
tropical  disease.  The  limited  statistical  data  available  suggest  that  the 
bulk  of  the  population  has  incomes  below  $75  per  annum  (see  Table 
23-5)  and  in  some  areas  incomes  are  falling.  Thus  per  capita  income  in 

TABLE  23-5 

Africa:  Per  Capita  National  Income  of  Selected  Countries  * 

(in  U.  S.  Dollars) 

COUNTRY  YEAR  AMOUNT 

Belgian  Congo 

Egypt 

Gold  Coast 

Kenya 

Nigeria 

Northern  Rhodesia 

Southern  Rhodesia 

Tunisia3 

Uganda 

Union  of  South  Africa 

a  Revue  D'Economie  Politique   (Paris,   March-April,   1954). 

*  United  Nations,  Statistics  of  National  Income  and  Expenditure,  Series  H,  No.  6   (New  York,  August, 
1954). 

Egypt  today  is  considerably  less  than  it  was  in  the  1920's.  Incomes  are 
distributed  very  unevenly  between  natives  and  Europeans.  Thus,  French- 
men in  North  Africa  are  generally  considered  to  enjoy  living  standards 
equal  to,  or  higher  than,  in  metropolitan  France  ($880  per  capita  Gross 
National  Product  in  1954).  The  relatively  small  white  populations  of  the 
Union  of  South  Africa  have  higher  average  incomes  than  in  most  Euro- 
pean countries.  Accordingly,  average  incomes  of  native  peoples  in  coun- 
tries where  Europeans  play  a  significant  economic  role  are  substantially 
less  than  shown.  An  economic  middle  class  is  virtually  unknown  in  native 

14  New  York  Times,  October  24,  1954. 


1951 

63 

1950 

121 

1950 

102 

1952 

52 

1950-51 

67 

1952 

89 

1952 

151 

1952 

100 

1952 

53 

1952 

272 

AFRICA:  THE  LAST  STAND  OF  COLONIALISM  703 

Africa  south  of  the  Sahara,  except  possibly  in  the  Belgian  Congo  and  the 
Gold  Coast.  Incomes  in  Nigeria,  which  is  a  predominantly  native  agricul- 
tural economy,  probably  are  fairly  representative  of  the  mass  of  Africa's 
population. 

Agriculture  is  the  principal  economic  activity  with  about  three-fourths 
of  the  population  of  the  continent  as  a  whole  dependent  on  farming  for 
a  livelihood,  as  compared  with  about  60  per  cent  for  South  America.  In 
most  countries  agriculture  accounts  for  40  to  55  per  cent  of  the  national 
income.  Except  for  the  Union  of  South  Africa,  manufacturing  generally 
accounts  for  10  per  cent  or  less  of  total  production.  Again,  outside  of  the 
Union,  most  progress  in  the  development  of  secondary  industry  has  been 
achieved  in  French  North  Africa,  chiefly  Algeria,  Egypt,  the  Belgian 
Congo,  Kenya,  and  Southern  Rhodesia.  Handicraft  industries  are  of  some 
significance  in  parts  of  West  Africa,  particularly  the  Gold  Coast  and  Ni- 
geria. Manufactures  follow  the  typical  pattern  for  underdeveloped  areas, 
with  primary  emphasis  on  consumer  goods  industries  like  textiles,  food 
packing,  and  the  processing  of  raw  materials  for  export.  The  production 
of  minerals  accounts  for  a  significant  percentage  of  total  output  in  a  few 
countries  like  the  Belgian  Congo,  Northern  and  Southern  Rhodesia,  and 
of  course  the  Union  of  South  Africa.  Most  industrial  and  commercial  en- 
terprises are  controlled  by  non-indigenous  elements.  For  example,  a  1952 
census  of  business  in  Tunisia  showed  that  90  per  cent  of  the  commercial 
and  industrial  establishments  employing  more  than  50  persons  were 
owned  by  non-Tunisians. 

Although  the  scope  of  the  money  economy  is  gradually  widening  in 
Africa  as  more  of  the  native  population  exchanges  its  production  or  labor 
for  cash,  subsistence  agriculture  is  still  of  primary  importance,  particu- 
larly in  the  middle  region.  The  United  Nations  has  estimated  that  in  all 
territories  of  Middle  Africa,  except  the  Gold  Coast,  subsistence  farming 
accounts  for  approximately  60  per  cent  or  more  of  the  total  land  area  cul- 
tivated by  the  native  population.15  In  many  areas  like  French  West  Africa, 
Kenya,  and  Southern  Rhodesia,  the  percentage  exceeds  80  per  cent.  The 
same  United  Nations  study  estimates  that  60  per  cent  of  the  adult  male 
population  is  engaged  in  subsistence  production.  In  certain  areas  like 
French  West  Africa,  the  Gold  Coast,  and  Nigeria,  cash  earning  chieflv 
takes  the  form  of  cash  cropping.  In  others  like  Kenya  and  Southern  Rho- 
desia, wage  earning  is  the  chief  source  of  native  money  income.  In  some 
territories  like  the  Belgian  Congo,  money  incomes  are  derived  both  from 

15  United  Nations,  Department  of  Economic  Affairs,  Enlargement  of  the  Exchange 
Economy  in  Tropical  Africa  ( New  York,  1954 ) ,  p.  13. 


704        THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

cash  cropping  and  wage  earning.  Wage  earning  activities  are  in  various 
stages  of  transition  from  intermittent  employment  for  wages  combined 
with  subsistence  farming  to  complete  dependence  on  wages.  The  growth 
of  the  wage-earning  class  has  been  greatest  in  areas  like  Kenya,  Northern 
Rhodesia,  and  Southern  Rhodesia  where  the  pressure  of  the  population 
on  the  land  has  forced  natives  to  seek  alternative  means  of  earning  a 
livelihood.  Nonetheless  labor  remains  scarce  in  many  parts  of  Africa,  and 
the  movement  of  labor  to  the  towns  and  mines  frequently  impairs  agricul- 
tural output. 

Production  methods  in  agriculture  among  the  native  populations  are 
extremely  primitive.  Yields  per  acre  and  per  man  are  the  lowest  of  all  the 
continents.  Food  crop  yields  per  acre  are  only  about  60  per  cent  of  the 
world  average.  Most  natives  employ  no  more  efficient  tool  than  the  hoe. 
While  a  few  are  learning  to  use  the  plough,  its  general  employment  in 
many  regions  is  impossible  because  the  tsetse  fly  precludes  the  use  of 
draft  animals.  Outside  of  a  few  areas  like  Egypt  and  French  North  Africa 
conservation  of  water  and  the  use  of  fertilizers  is  rare.  Agricultural  output 
also  suffers  from  the  fact  that  many  parts  of  Africa  are  subject  to  periodic 
drought  and  famine. 

Like  other  underdeveloped  regions,  exports  of  a  few  primary  products 
account  for  the  preponderant  share  of  total  exports  in  most  countries. 
Thus  in  1952  cotton  accounted  for  87  per  cent  of  the  value  of  Egypt's 
exports,  copper  for  almost  90  per  cent  of  the  value  of  Northern  Rhodesia's 
exports,  and  cocoa  for  60  per  cent  of  the  Gold  Coast's  exports.  As  a  result, 
levels  of  income  are  subject  to  wide  fluctuations  depending  on  external 
market  conditions.  Intra-African  trade  is  small.  In  1948  only  13  per  cent 
of  Africa's  exports  were  intra-regional.16  The  chief  reasons  for  this  low 
figure  are  ( 1 )  the  exports  of  most  of  the  territories  are  competing  rather 
than  complementary,  (2)  trade  is  largely  oriented  overseas  because  of 
the  strength  of  colonial  ties,  and  (3)  transport  and  communications  are 
very  poor. 

Africa  has  a  poorly  developed  transport  system.  Human  porterage  is 
still  of  importance  in  tropical  Africa  for  the  movement  of  goods  over  short 
distances.  Relatively  few  areas  outside  of  French  North  Africa  and  the 
Union  of  South  Africa  are  adequately  served  by  rail,  road,  or  river  com- 
munications (cf.  Fig.  23-1,  p.  690).  Lack  of  transport  is  a  major  obstacle 
to  the  development  of  most  of  Africa.  In  1949,  the  total  length  of  Africa's 
rail  network  (excluding  Egypt)  was  only  about  39,000  miles,  of  which 

16  "Summary  of  World  Trade  Statistics,"  United  Nations  Statistical  Papers,  Series  D, 
No.  2  (New  York,  April,  1950). 


AFRICA:  THE  LAST  STAND  OF  COLONIALISM  705 

roughly  one-half  was  concentrated  in  French  North  Africa  and  the  Union 
of  South  Africa.17  Railway  development,  particularly  in  Middle  Africa, 
occurred  largely  in  response  to  the  need  to  transport  minerals  from  the 
interior  to  the  coast  for  export  abroad  (cf.  Fig.  7-6,  p.  186).  In  many  cases 
the  servicing  of  agricultural  communities  is  thus  largely  fortuitous.  In- 
ternal crosswise  rail  development  is  insignificant.  "Such  transcontinental 
connections  as  the  Cape  to  Cairo  Railway  or  the  Trans-Saharian  were 
partially  built  or  projected  to  serve  national  and  imperial  schemes  and  not 
necessarily  to  respond  to  strictly  economic  criteria."  1S  Few  highways  in 
tropical  Africa  are  hard-surfaced  and  most  are  impassable  during  the 
rainy  season.  Natural  obstacles,  such  as  falls  and  rapids  close  to  their 
mouths,  and  seasonal  fluctuations  in  the  flow,  place  severe  limitations  on 
the  use  of  Africa's  rivers  for  transportation  purposes.  Except  for  the  Nile 
and  Congo  river  systems,  river  transport  is  largely  limited  to  the  navigable 
lakes  like  Nyasa  and  Victoria.19 

CONTRASTING  COLONIAL  POLICIES 

Marked  differences  are  to  be  found  in  the  colonial  policies  which  the 
European  metropoles  pursue  in  their  African  dependencies.  Very  fre- 
quently these  policies  reflect  strong  geographical  influences.  The  British 
officially  proclaim  the  primacy  of  the  interests  of  the  native  populations 
and  seek  to  encourage  the  development  of  self-government  in  their  terri- 
tories. In  the  Belgian  colonies  a  paternalistic  attitude  toward  the  native 
population  still  governs  colonial  policy  and  the  emphasis  is  on  efficiency 
and  maximum  returns  for  the  mother  country.  Neither  the  native  nor  the 
white  populations  have  political  rights.  Preparation  for  self-govern- 
ment is  viewed  as  a  goal  for  the  more  distant  future  after  the  natives  have 
been  civilized.  Portugal's  colonial  policies  are  somewhat  similar,  except 
that  Angola  and  Mozambique  are  considered  overseas  provinces  of  Por- 
tugal rather  than  colonies.  French  policy  looks  toward  the  gradual  inte- 
gration of  its  African  dependencies  into  the  French  Union  on  a  basis  of 
common  citizenship  and  unified  political  institutions  as  in  Algeria.  In  the 
case  of  Tunisia  and  Morocco,  however,  the  French  are  being  compelled  to 
grant  independence  outside  the  framework  of  the  French  Union. 

British  policies  have  brought  dependencies  like  the  Gold  Coast  and 
Nigeria,  well  along  the  path  toward  self-government.  This  process  has 

17  United  Nations,  Review  of  Economic  Conditions  In  Africa  (New  York,  1951). 

18  Haines,  op.  cit.,  p.  129. 

19  Hailey,  op.  cit.,  p.  1541. 


706       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

been  facilitated  by  the  absence  of  any  significant  numbers  of  European 
settlers  in  these  territories,  thereby  minimizing  the  inevitable  clash 
of  interests  between  the  natives  and  the  whites.  However,  these  same 
conditions  do  not  obtain  in  many  parts  of  British  Central  and  East 
Africa.  Here  more  favorable  climatic  conditions  have  attracted  moderate 
numbers  of  white  settlers,  who  favor  a  policy  of  white  supremacy.  The 
result  has  been  increasing  social  tensions  and  in  certain  instances  serious 
physical  outbursts  like  the  Mau  Mau  disturbances  in  Kenya  described 
elsewhere. 

British  policy  has  favored  the  federation  and  consolidation  of  its  African 
territories.  The  first  move  in  this  direction  has  been  the  creation  of  the  Cen- 
tral African  Federation  in  1953  comprising  Northern  and  Southern  Rhode- 
sia and  Nyasaland.  Political  considerations  figured  most  importantly  in  the 
establishment  of  the  Federation,  but  the  desire  to  create  a  more  cohesive 
economic  unit  combining  three  essentially  economically  interdependent 
political  units  was  a  contributory  factor.  While  the  white  minorities  fa- 
vored the  Federation,  it  was  bitterly  opposed  by  the  natives  in  all  three 
territories.  They  fear  that  the  resultant  improvement  in  economic  condi- 
tions will  attract  additional  white  settlers  and  add  to  the  pressure  on  the 
natives.  Conflicting  racial  interests  block  a  proposed  similar  federation  of 
Uganda,  Kenya,  and  Tanganyika.  Efforts  to  organize  tropical  Africa  along 
regional  lines  to  take  into  account  natural  resources  and  communications 
are  a  recognition  of  the  limitations  of  the  original  colonial  boundaries. 

Thus  far  Belgian  policies  in  the  Congo  have  been  highly  successful  in 
maintaining  political  stability.  Unlike  the  Union  of  South'  Africa  and  Brit- 
ish East  Africa,  the  Congo  has  no  color  bar.  Natives  are  permitted  and 
encouraged  to  train  for  and  occupy  skilled  positions.  The  size  of  the  white 
population  is  limited  and  there  are  few  permanent  settlers.  Political  rights 
of  both  whites  and  natives  are  barred  as  noted  above,  although  the  Bel- 
gians are  planning  to  give  the  right  to  everyone  to  vote  in  municipal  elec- 
tions. Just  how  long  this  situation  can  continue  is  uncertain.  There  is  the 
periodic  pressure  from  Belgian  groups  who  want  to  send  out  large  num- 
bers of  white  settlers  to  the  Congo.  If  these  efforts  were  realized  the  result 
could  be  a  breakdown  of  the  present  system  and  the  development  of  con- 
ditions similar  to  those  in  some  British  territories.  Then  there  is  always  the 
possibility  that  the  growth  of  native  self-government  in  neighboring  terri- 
tories will  generate  similar  pressure  in  the  Congo. 

In  French  West  Africa  political  conditions  are  still  relatively  tranquil, 
but  as  in  the  Congo  there  is  always  the  prospect  that  growing  native  as- 
pirations for  self-government  will  intensify.  In  French  North  Africa,  with 


AFRICA:  THE  LAST  STAND  OF  COLONIALISM  707 

its  sizable  European  minority,  the  conflict  of  interests  between  the  natives 
and  whites  and  the  growing  demands  of  the  natives  for  greater  political 
and  economic  freedom  created  a  highly  explosive  political  situation.  As  a 
result  France  has  been  forced  to  agree  to  grant  independence  to  Morocco 
and  Tunisia  and  certain  economic  and  social  reforms  to  Algeria.  Portu- 
guese territories  enjoy  relative  political  stability  as  a  result  of  strict  gov- 
ernment controls,  the  small  white  population,  and  the  fact  that  the  process 
of  modernization  has  not  gone  very  far  due  to  the  limited  resources  for 
economic  development  at  the  disposal  of  the  Portuguese  government. 

AGRICULTURE 

Since  World  War  II,  total  agricultural  output  in  Africa  as  well  as  output 
of  foodstuffs  has  increased  somewhat  more  rapidly  than  the  population. 
This  has  permitted  some  raising  of  the  very  low  prewar  per  capita  levels 
of  food  consumption  as  well  as  a  considerable  expansion  of  exports.  How- 
ever, most  of  the  improvement  in  diets  probably  has  been  limited  to  the 
Union  of  South  Africa  and  the  more  prosperous  cocoa  and  mineral-pro- 
ducing regions.  Africa  produces  the  bulk  of  its  essential  food  needs,  al- 
though the  margin  between  supplies  and  requirements  is  narrowing.  Thus, 
whereas  Africa  before  the  war  had  an  export  surplus  of  cereals  of  about 
three-quarters  of  a  million  tons  per  annum,  it  is  now  running  a  slight 
deficit  largely  because  of  Egypt's  sizable  imports  and  reduced  surpluses 
from  French  North  Africa. 

Principal  Crops.  Africa  displays  considerable  variation  from  region  to 
region  with  respect  to  the  principal  crops,  production  for  the  home  mar- 
ket and  for  export,  methods  of  cultivation,  and  farm  agricultural  organiza- 
tion. In  French  North  Africa  the  principal  food  crops  are  wheat  and 
barley,  in  Egypt  wheat,  corn,  and  rice.  South  of  the  Sahara  wheat  is  of 
almost  negligible  importance  except  in  the  Union  of  South  Africa.  Root 
crops,  millets,  sorghum,  pulses,  and  maize  are  of  greatest  significance. 
Root  crops  are  particularly  important  in  tropical  areas.  In  certain  terri- 
tories, the  proportion  of  cultivated  land  devoted  to  the  production  of 
export  crops  represents  a  large  percentage  of  the  total.  The  Gold  Coast 
with  45  per  cent  is  a  notable  example.  Countries  where  the  area  under 
crops  mainly  for  export  range  between  20  and  30  per  cent  include  Egvpt, 
French  Equatorial  Africa,  and  Uganda.  In  some  areas  high  prices  for 
export  crops  have  reduced  production  of  food  for  local  consumption.  This 
could  create  serious  food  deficiencies  in  periods  of  rapidly  declining  ex- 
port prices.    (The  principal  agricultural  exports  were  given  in  Table 


708       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

23-4.)  Although  Africa  is  believed  to  have  significant  potentialities  for 
increasing  meat  production,  cattle-raising  is  presently  of  only  limited  eco- 
nomic significance.  In  tropical  Africa  a  major  limitation,  as  mentioned 
earlier,  is  the  widespread  presence  of  the  tsetse  fly.  Purely  nomadic  tribes 
are  found  chiefly  in  the  savanna  region  on  the  southern  border  of  the 
Sahara. 

Land  Tenure.  Although  landlordism  is  much  less  of  a  problem  in  Africa 
than  in  other  underdeveloped  regions,  the  continent  nonetheless  faces 
serious  difficulties  in  certain  areas  arising  out  of  existing  land  tenure  ar- 
rangements. Communal  tenure  is  the  most  widespread  form  of  agricul- 
tural organization  in  Africa  south  of  the  Sahara.  While  it  manifests  itself 
in  a  variety  of  forms  communal  tenure  has  a  number  of  common  features. 
"Land  is  held  on  a  tribal,  village,  kindred  or  family  basis,  and  individuals 
have  definite  rights  in  this  land  by  virtue  of  their  membership  in  the  rele- 
vant social  unit.  Hence,  title  to  land  has  a  communal  character  and  it  is 
usufructuary,  rather  than  absolute." 20  Subsistence  shifting-cultivation 
usually  is  associated  with  communal  forms  of  land  tenure. 

A  number  of  developments  that  vary  in  importance  from  region  to 
region  are  breaking  up  this  traditional  system  of  land  tenure  and  cultiva- 
tion. Shifting  agriculture,  as  described  on  page  697,  requires  a  plentiful 
supply  of  land.  However,  with  the  growth  of  population  the  pressure  of 
numbers  on  the  land  has  made  more  intensive  methods  of  cultivation 
necessary.  This  has  frequently  led  to  overcropping  and  soil  exhaustion. 
It  has  forced  increasing  numbers  of  natives  to  seek  employment  on  Euro- 
pean-owned plantations  and  in  industry  as  an  alternative  or  supplemen- 
tary source  of  income.  This  process  has  been  intensified  by  the  earlier 
colonial  land  alienation  policies.  In  French  Equatorial  Africa  and  the 
Belgian  Congo  vast  territories  were  declared  vacant  by  the  state  and 
turned  over  to  private  concessions.  This  resulted  from  a  misunderstanding 
of  the  fact  that  seemingly  vacant  lands  were  in  fact  cultivable  tribal  areas 
lying  fallow.  Subsequently  the  concessions  originally  granted  were  con- 
siderably reduced  and  government  policies  were  adopted  to  encourage 
native  freeholds.  In  the  Union  of  South  Africa,  Kenya,  and  Northern 
Rhodesia,  reserves  of  land  were  set  aside  for  the  native  population.  How- 
ever, these  reserves  were  wholly  inadequate  under  existing  methods  of 
cultivation. 

The  shortage  of  land  and  the  reserve  system  has  been  a  major  cause  of 
Kenya's  Mau  Mau  uprisings.  Roughly  4,000  white  settlers  occupy  the 

20  United  Nations,  Land  Reform  (New  York,  1951). 


AFRICA:  THE  LAST  STAND  OF  COLONIALISM  709 

12,000-square-mile  fertile  belt  of  the  green  highlands  of  Kenya  where 
Negroes  cannot  acquire  land.  By  contrast  the  Kikuyu  tribe  of  1,2.50,000 
persons  is  restricted  to  2,000  square  miles.  Land  hunger  is  intense.  The 
pressure  of  population  on  this  limited  area  has  made  it  necessary  for  about 
200,000  natives  to  work  on  plantations  and  in  other  employments  on  the 
white  reserve.  This  is  back  of  the  Mau  Mau's  determination  to  drive  the 
white  man  out. 

The  growth  of  cash  cropping  by  which  land  acquires  a  commercial 
value  is  also  contributing  to  the  break-up  of  the  communal  system  of 
land  tenure.  This  process  has  gone  further  in  Uganda  and  the  Belgian 
Congo  where  the  desire  to  exploit  land  for  commercial  purposes  has  pro- 
moted widespread  individual  forms  of  land  ownership.  Also  important 
has  been  the  growing  demand  for  labor  resulting  from  the  expanding 
production  of  minerals  and  agricultural  products  for  export.  A  growing 
number  of  natives  have  abandoned  subsistence  agriculture  to  become  in- 
dustrial and  agricultural  wage  earners. 

In  certain  parts  of  Africa,  particularly  eastern  central  and  southern, 
there  has  been  some  development  of  plantation  agriculture  mainly  by 
Europeans.  Crops  consist  mostly  of  export  products  such  as  sisal,  sugar, 
coffee,  tobacco,  and  rubber.  Because  of  the  early  difficulties  of  attracting 
native  labor  some  of  these  plantations  were  developed  by  immigrant 
labor.  The  most  notable  example  was  the  use  of  Indians  on  the  Natal 
sugar  plantations.  After  serving  their  period  of  indentured  service  many 
of  these  Indians  stayed  on  in  Natal  to  engage  in  market-gardening  and 
retail  trade.  This  has  given  rise  to  a  color  problem  in  the  Union  of  South 
Africa  second  only  to  that  of  the  Negro  problem,  a  problem  which  has 
been  the  cause  of  serious  strictures  between  the  Union  of  South  African 
Government  and  the  Government  of  India. 

In  French  North  Africa  and  Egypt  individual  ownership  in  property 
is  well  developed  and  landlordism  is  a  problem.  Thus  in  Tunisia,  the 
French  hold  25  per  cent  of  the  land  devoted  to  crops  although  they  repre- 
sent less  than  7  per  cent  of  the  population.  Moreover,  these  are  the  most 
fertile  and  best-watered  lands.  Natives  generally  farm  small  uneconomic 
plots.  This  situation  may  well  change  if  the  French  pull  out  in  the  face 
of  growing  local  instability  and  pressures.  Until  the  land  reform  law  of 
September,  1952,  one-half  of  one  per  cent  of  Egypt's  population  owned 
one-third  of  the  land  in  holdings  of  50  acres  or  more.  Another  one-third  of 
the  land  was  owned  by  5  to  6  per  cent  of  the  population  in  plots  of  5  or 
more  but  less  than  50  acres.  The  remaining  one-third  was  controlled  by 


710       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

94  per  cent  of  the  landowners  in  plots  averaging  under  one  acre.21  Under 
the  land  reform  program  almost  600,000  acres  of  land  are  to  be  taken  from 
1,758  landowners  and  distributed  to  250,000  families  over  a  period  of  five 
years.22  While  the  program  has  improved  the  lot  of  the  peasant  families 
affected,  it  by  no  means  has  destroyed  the  wealthy  land-owning  class  or 
solved  the  basic  problem  of  land  hunger. 

For  most  of  Africa,  however,  the  poverty  of  the  natives  is  chiefly  a 
result  of  the  primitive  methods  of  farming,  which  lead  to  food  shortages 
and  land  exhaustion,  rather  than  the  system  of  land  tenure.  One  promising 
approach  to  the  introduction  of  better  farming  and  better  land  use  is  the 
so-called  settlement  scheme.  "They  are  . .  .  the  means  of  settling  either 
land  reclaimed  from  bush  and  waste,  or  reclaimed  from  aridity  by  irriga- 
tion, or  land  lately  used  by  Africans  to  the  point  of  exhaustion  and  re- 
habilitated by  proper  fallowing,  manuring  and  similar  treatment,  and 
then  laid  out  in  proper  holdings,  bunded  strip  cropped  or  otherwise 
treated  to  prevent  soil  erosion,  etc.  and  settlement  by  peasants."  23  An 
outstanding  example  is  the  Gezira  Scheme  in  the  Sudan  which  embraces 
one  million  acres  with  irrigation  canals.  The  Scheme  is  a  partnership 
between  the  government  and  the  peasant  who  share  the  profits  and  the 
responsibilities  for  maintaining  the  land.  The  government  furnishes  the 
land  to  the  peasant  in  forty-acre  plots  on  a  long-term  lease  basis  and  is 
responsible  for  the  supply  of  water.  It  also  provides  qualified  agricultural 
managers,  mechanical  equipment,  fertilizers,  and  marketing  facilities.  The 
peasant  on  his  part  is  required  to  observe  proper  methods  of  cultivation. 
Through  their  representatives  the  peasants  have  assumed  an  increasing 
role  in  running  the  project.  The  Gezira  Scheme  has  been  highly  successful 
and  similar  projects  have  been  established  in  a  number  of  other  territories. 
The  settlement  scheme  would  appear  to  offer  considerable  opportunities 
for  improving  the  lot  of  the  native  populations. 

LONG-RUN  ECONOMIC  PROSPECTS 

Since  World  War  II  government-sponsored  long-range  economic  devel- 
opment plans  have  been  drawn  up  for  most  African  territories  and  in 
many  areas  these  plans  are  now  being  implemented.  In  the  case  of  the 
dependent  territories  a  large  proportion  of  the  funds  is  being  provided 
by  the  metropoles.  By  and  large  these  plans  provide  for  investments 

21  Department  of  State,  Agriculture  In  Point  Four  Countries,  Part  4,  Near  East  and 
Independent  Africa  (August,  1952),  p.  1. 

22  New  York  Times,  October  20,  1955. 

23  United  Nations,  Progress  In  Land  Reform  (New  York,  1954),  p.  107. 


AFRICA:  THE  LAST  STAND  OF  COLONIALISM  711 

which  are  unlikely  to  attract  private  capital  and  yet  are  fairly  basic  to  the 
achievement  of  any  real  economic  progress.  The  principal  categories  of 
investment  include  irrigation,  transportation,  social  services  like  educa- 
tion, health,  public  housing,  and  measures  to  increase  agricultural  pro- 
ductivity. While  the  programs  seek  to  stimulate  production  of  primary 
products  required  by  the  metropole  they  show  much  more  concern  for 
the  welfare  of  the  native  population  than  earlier  colonial  policies.  Despite 
these  plans  there  is  still  no  evidence  of  a  significant  acceleration  of  eco- 
nomic growth  in  most  parts  of  Africa. 

Before  economic  development  can  proceed  very  rapidly  in  Africa 
among  the  native  populations,  more  resources  will  have  to  be  shifted 
from  subsistence  to  exchange  activities  and  productivity  will  have  to  be 
greatly  increased.  Otherwise  the  incentives  and  the  means  of  providing 
surpluses  required  to  feed  workers  in  industry  and  to  accumulate  capital 
will  be  lacking.  New  techniques  of  farming  will  have  to  be  developed  to 
counteract  the  declining  productivity  of  the  soil  and  permit  settled  agri- 
culture. The  failure  of  the  Tanganyika  Groundnut  Scheme  is  a  good  ex- 
ample of  the  difficulties  of  introducing  new  methods  of  cultivation  in 
tropical  regions  even  where  large-scale  financial  backing  is  available.  A 
fundamental  attack  will  have  to  be  made  against  the  problem  of  disease. 
There  are  many  obstacles  to  the  development  of  industry.  An  entrepre- 
neurial class  will  have  to  develop.  A  disciplined  and  trained  labor  force 
has  to  be  established.  Levels  of  literacy  will  have  to  be  raised.  Even  the 
present  limited  development  programs  are  greatly  hampered  by  the  lack 
of  skilled  workers  and  adequately  trained  administrators.  Then  there  is 
the  problem  of  native-white  relations  in  some  areas.  Thus,  much  of  Africa 
has  a  considerable  way  to  travel  before  it  faces  the  no  less  serious  prob- 
lem of  capital  shortage.  Very  few  of  the  native  economies  have  the 
capacity  to  mobilize  significant  amounts  of  capital  for  investment.  While 
the  present  expansion  of  basic  services  under  government  auspices  will 
attract  private  capital  into  industry,  mining,  and  agriculture,  not  much  of 
this  capital  is  likely  to  move  into  the  native  economy.  Thus  the  native 
economies  may  benefit  from  the  present  programs  only  indirectly.  There 
are  some  exceptions,  of  course,  like  the  Gold  Coast  which  has  accumu- 
lated large  sums  for  development  through  its  cocoa  stabilization  fund,  and 
the  Belgian  Congo  with  its  profitable  mineral  export  industries.  Some 
countries,  like  Egypt,  may  be  unable  to  expand  output  rapidly  enough  to 
keep  pace  with  the  growth  of  population.  For  most  of  the  region,  how- 
ever, economic  development  is  likely  to  be  slow  and  production  of  food- 
stuffs and  industrial  raw  materials  will  continue  to  predominate.  Perhaps 


712       THE  ECONOMIC  FACTOR  IN  POLITICAL  GEOGRAPHY 

the  outlook  for  Africa  is  well  summed  up  in  the  following  statement  by 
Albion  Ross  in  his  previously  mentioned  series  of  articles  on  Africa:  24 

The  drama  of  the  Americas  will  never  be  re-enacted  here  unless  the  findings 
of  the  geographers,  soil  scientists  and  the  like  are  all  wrong.  The  theory  of  the 
"dying  continent"  is  probably  regarded  today  by  African  soil  scientists  as  some- 
what of  an  exaggeration  but  they  grant  that  it  contains  a  vital  element  of  truth. 
The  native  will  need  all  of  his  African  heritage  as  the  generations  go  by  and 
will  be  lucky  if  it  can  support  him  in  decency. 

24  New  York  Times,  October  26,  1954. 


w 


ex 


The  Index  is  not  meant  to  list  every  geographical  place  name  mentioned  in 
the  text.  Rather,  it  attempts  to  list  subject  matters,  place  names,  and  names 
of  persons  which  have  been  given  substantial  treatment;  even  with  this  limita- 
tion, the  great  variety  of  subjects  covered  in  the  text  precludes  a  complete 
indexing. 


Acheson,  Dean,  272 

Aden:  strategic  base  of,  235 

Afghanistan,  89;  language  factors,  394  f.; 
Soviet  penetration,  619 

Africa:  agricultural  land,  696  f.;  agricul- 
ture, 702,  707  ff.;  area,  691  f.;  climate, 
694  f.;  colonial  policies,  705  ff.;  crops, 
707  f.;  economic  significance,  696  ff.; 
exports,  704;  European  minorities,  347; 
forests,  698;  immigration,  374  f.,  692; 
land  tenure,  708  ff.;  manufacturing, 
703;  minerals,  698  f.;  population, 
691  f.;  prospects,  710  ff.;  railroads  in 
Central  Africa,  186  (map),  690  (map); 
resources  690  (map),  696  ff.;  stra- 
tegic significance,  700  f.;  transporta- 
tion, 704  f. 

Afrikaans  language,  391 

Agriculture:  China,  503  ff.,  511  f.,  512  ff.; 
Japan,  525,  526;  U.S.S.R.,  489  ff.; 
Western  Europe,  539,  542,  547  f., 
560  f. 

Air  distances   ( across  Arctic ) ,  247  ff . 

Alaska,  non-contiguity,  66 

Alaskan  Panhandle,  75 

Alexander  VI,  255  f. 

Algeria,  as  part  of  France,  66 

Amazon  Basin,  settlement  of,  300,  673 

Amazon  River,  187,  673 

"American  Ruhr,"  166 

Amery,  L.  S.,  449,  450 

Ancel,  J.,  136 

Andhra,  385,  387 

Angola,  58 

Ankara,  as  capital,  144  f. 

Antarctic:  claims,  84  (map);  narrow 
marine  straits  in  the,  245 

Anti-Colonialism  (Colombo  Powers),  289 

Appalachians,  language  islands,  399 

Apartheid,  60  f. 


Appenzell,  Swiss  canton  and  exclave,  60 

Arab  countries,  population,  298 

Arable  land,  world,  462  (map) 

Arctic  Mediterranean,  246  ff.;  strategic 
bases  in,  251,  278 

Arctic  Ocean,  182  f.,  246  ff.;  sector  prin- 
ciple, 126   (map) 

Arctic  Sea  routes,  251 

Arctic,  air  routes,  246  (map);  coloniza- 
tion, 220;  population  factors,  300;  stra- 
tegic factors,  220  f .,  248  ( map ) 

Argentina  ( see  also  South  America ) :  in 
the  Antarctic,  245;  and  Chilean  bound- 
ary, 92  (map);  Manifest  Destiny,  268; 
and  Western  Hemisphere,  267  f.;  im- 
migration, 370;  industrialization,  617; 
location  of  capital,  152  f. 

Asia,  Mackinder's  concept  of,  213  f.;  pop- 
ulation transfers,  363 

Asian  countries,  population,  297,  298 

Asian  Frontier  Zones,  linguistic  divides, 
394  f. 

Atomic  energy  resources,  456  (map); 
Western  Europe,  559 

Atoms  for  Peace  Plan,  621  ff. 

Australia:  capital,  151;  in  the  Antarc- 
tic, 246;  continental  shelf,  49  (map); 
empty  spaces,  131;  immigration,  370; 
immigration  policy,  375;  urban  drift, 
354,  371 

Autarky,  485 

Azores,  66 


"Backdoors,"  180 
Baghdad  Treaty,  285  f. 
Baikal-Amur  Railway,  221 
Balance  of  power,  218  f. 
Baldwin,  H.  W.,  244  f. 
Bali  Strait,  233 


713 


714 


INDEX 


Balkan  Treaty,  1954,  282 

Baltic  Sea,  237  ff.,  238  (map);  U.S.S.R. 
control  of,  239 

Baltic  Straits,  234 

Bandung  Conference,  289  (map),  384, 
610 

Basel  Airport,  62 

Bases  Overseas,  U.S.,  275  ff. 

Basutoland,  an  exclave,  60,  61  (map) 

Bates,  M.,  459 

Beaufort  Sea,  58,  183,  251 

Benelux,  132,  557  f. 

Bengal,  387;  migrations,  363  f.;  language, 
388 

Bering  Strait,  237,  251 

Berlin,  117;  core  character  of,  156;  as  ex- 
clave, 63,  64  (map) 

Birth  rates,  declining,  338 

Black,  E.,  610 

Black  Sea,  243 

Blockade  of  Heartland  power,  242  ff. 

Boer  States,  boundaries,  176,  177  (map) 

Boers,  391 

Boggs,  S.  W.,  267 

Bohemia,  location,  203  f. 

Bolivia,  181  (map) 

Bolshevik,  494 

Bombay,  234;  language  factors,  387 

Bonn,  as  capital,  157 

Boundaries:  Alaskan-Siberian,  102  f.;  and 
population  pressures,  128  ff.;  Antarctic, 
82;  antecedent,  89;  Arctic,  83;  arti- 
ficial, 94  f.;  barrier  function,  85  f.; 
changes,  107;  crystallized,  109;  demar- 
cation of,  90;  diminishing  functions  of, 
111;  emotional  value  of,  123  f.;  func- 
tions of,  85;  49°  boundary,  104,  105; 
geometrical,  85,  104;  marked  by  physi- 
cal features,  95;  mountain  crest,  95; 
natural,  94;  obsolescence  of,  112;  of 
small  economic  units,  obsolescence, 
132;  of  Soviet  satellites,  133;  of  terri- 
torial states,  vs.  national  states,  138; 
religious,  411,  417;  superimposed,  94; 
survival  of,  121;  subterranean,  135; 
undefined,  89  f.;  zone,  87  ff. 

Boundary  lines,  and  boundary  zones,  79; 
conflicts  in  South  America,  180  (map); 
De  facto,  81;  definition,  80;  De  jure, 
81;  disputed,  81;  types  of,  81 

Brandenburg,  fragmented  and  contigu- 
ous territory,  64  f . 

Braunschweig,  fragmented  state,  62 

Bratislava  bridgehead,  98  ( map ) 

Brazil  (see  also  South  America),  674, 
676;  shift  of  capitals,  151  f.,  152 
(map);  size,  comparative,  44  (map) 


Britain,  in  the  Antarctic,  245 

British  Commonwealth  of  Nations,  immi- 
gration and  emigration  trends,  375 

British  control  of  Indian  Ocean  terri- 
tories, 69 

British  Isles,  200 

British  naval  bases,  234  f . 

Buddhism,  distribution  of,  420  (map) 

Buenos  Aires,  growth  of,  152  f. 

Buffer  states,  176  ff.,  179  (map) 

Burgess,  J.  W.,  11 

Biisingen,  German  exclave,  61 


Cabinda,  185;  Portuguese  exclave,  58 

Calcutta,  188 

California:     core    area    of,     169  ff.;     170 

(map);  population  movement  to,  572 
Campione,  Italian  exclave,  61 
Canada:  agriculture,  596,  598;  economic 

capabilities,  593  ff.;  foreign  trade,  599; 

forests,    597;    geography    and    people, 

594  ff.;  hydroelectric  powers,  498;  im- 
migration, 370,  375;  languages,  geog- 
raphy of,  390,  391  (map);  minerals, 
597;    population    factors,    48     (map), 

595  f.;  resources,  47,  596  ff.;  rivers, 
594;  and  Western  Hemisphere,  259 

Canberra,  as  capital,  151 

Capital  cities  (see  also  Core  Areas),  143 

Capital  of  states,  shift  inland,  188 

Capitals:  location,  stability  of  as  core 
areas,  146  f.;  in  Turkey,  144  f.;  in 
U.S.S.R.,  148;  near  frontiers,  157;  and 
population  clusters  in  South  America, 
149  f. 

Capitulations,  65 

Caprivi  Strip,  75 

Caribbean  Area,  228,  72  (map) 

Caribbean  Sea  and  Panama  Canal,  237 

Carlson,  F.  A.,  268 

Caucasus,  petroleum,  477 

Central  Africa:  German  and  Portuguese 
expansion,  75  (map);  landlocked  posi- 
tion, 185,  187 

Central  African  Federation,  706 

Central  America,  resources,  670 

Central  Europe:  mass  migrations,  355  ff.; 
transfers  of  populations,  355  ff.;  forced 
migrations,  355  ff . 

Ceylon,  200,  201;  Indian  minority,  381; 
British  strategic  base  on,  235 

Chapultepec,  Act  of,  270  f . 

"Character"  of  Nations,  24 

Chile:  and  Argentina  boundary,  91 
(map);  in  the  Antarctic,  245;  elon- 
gated shape  of,  73 


INDEX 


715 


China:  expansion  of,  50;  agriculture, 
503  f.,  511  f.,  516;  arable  lands,  499  f.; 
capitals,  153  f.,  154  (map);  collectivi- 
zation of  agriculture,  512  f.;  compari- 
son with  other  economies,  508  f.;  core 
areas,  153,  301;  economic  relations 
with  U.S.S.R.,  514  f.,  516  f.;  economy, 
general  features,  495  f.;  foreign  trade, 
507,  514  f.;  "Forward  Points  of 
Growth,"  73  f.;  geographical  regions, 
496  ff.;  geography  of  dialects,  403, 
404  (map);  gross  national  product, 
508  f.,  513  f.;  industrial  and  economic 
growth,  507  ff.;  industry  and  trade, 
505  ff. ;  mineral  resources  and  energy, 
500  f.;  natural  resources,  499  ff.;  popu- 
lation, 297,  495,  500;  population  dis- 
tribution, 301;  principal  cities,  496, 
497;  rivers,  496,  497,  501;  trade  with 
Free  World,  614;  transportation,  226, 
498  (map),  501  ff.,  517 

China  Sea,  231 

Chinese:  in  Malaya,  379;  overseas, 
379  ff. 

Chou  En-lai,  506,  507,  509,  513 

Churches:  political  events,  influence  on, 
437  f. 

Circum-marine  states,  57  ff.,  157;  and 
strategic  bases,  69  ff. 

City  states,  size  of,  32  ff.,  33  ( map ) 

Clark,  C,  575 

Climate:  and  economic  development, 
458  f.;  and  population  growth,  459  f.; 
Canada,  594;  China,  496,  497;  cool 
temperate  regions,  460,  461;  Japan, 
523;  tropical  regions,  459;  U.S.S.R., 
473,  474;  Western  Europe,  537, 
538 

Coastal  bases,  188 

Coasts:  accessibility  to  invasion,  127, 
198  ff.;  as  boundaries,  124;  vulner- 
ability to  intrusion,  126 

Collective  Security,  279,  281  ff. 

Colombo  Plan,  287 

Colombo  Powers,  286  ff.,  287  (map) 

Colonies:  and  fragmented  shape,  65; 
European,  532  ff.,  551 

Colonization:  and  city  states,  34  ff.;  and 
geography  of  languages,  400  f. 

Colorado  River  Project,  579  f . 

Communications  in  boundary  zones, 
118  f. 

Communist  World  and  United  States, 
comparison  of  geography  and  economic 
factors,  471  f. 

Commuting,  across  boundaries,  118 

Compactness,  factor  of,  67 


Congo,  outlet,  185;  basin,  300;  State, 
location,  185,  123  (map);  coloniza- 
tion, 706 

Contiguous  and  non-contiguous  state 
areas,  58  ff. 

Continental  Shelf,  101,  102,  124,  125 
(map) 

Core  Areas,  142  ff.;  and  capital  cities, 
143  ff.;  and  colonialism,  172;  and 
shipping  lanes,  163  ff.;  competitive,  in 
outlying  regions,  169;  effect  of  com- 
munications on,  157  ff.;  in  regional 
geography,  142;  in  totalitarian  coun- 
tries, 171;  measures  aimed  at  reducing 
influence  of,  168  f.;  the  "natural"  core, 
149;  in  Israel,  Turkey,  South  America, 
and  Japan,  147,  144,  150,  155  (map) 

Corridors:  Finnish,  77  Polish,  77 

"Cost  Distance,"  260  f. 

Croats,  and  Catholicism,  431  f. 

Cross-boundary  influences,  120 

Cultural  factors,  440  ff. 

Cumberland  Road,  586 

Curzon,  G.  N.,  7 

Custom  Unions,  557  f . 

Czechoslovakia:  factor  of  shape,  71,  73; 
minorities  problems,  359  f.;  railroads 
of,  161,  162  (map);  schism  from 
Roman  Catholic  Church,  438;  spatial 
relationship  to  Germany,  76;  "threat" 
to  Nazi  Germany,  77   (map) 


Damao,  Portuguese  possession,  62 

Danish  Sound,  190 

Dano-Norwegian  language,  385 

Danube  River,  184,  545  f.;  international 
status,  184,  546 

Danzig,  77,  239,  32  (map) 

Dardanelles,  190,  624,  640 

Death   rates,   declining,   337  f. 

Debenham,  F.,  441 

de  la  Blache,  V.,  342 

Delhi,  refugees,  364 

Demographic  factors,  see  Population 

Demographic  types,  321 

Denmark,  strategic  location,  239 

Deserts:  as  boundary  in  Southern  Arabia, 
87;  divisive  factors  of,  67,  204 

Determinism,  4 

Detroit,  Michigan,  55   (map) 

DeVoto,  B.,  22 

Dialects,  and  political  geography  of  lan- 
guages, 402  ff . 

Displaced  persons,  371  ff. 

Dollar:  area,  563,  564;  "Gap,"  550, 
563  ff. 


716 


INDEX 


Drake  Passage,  245,  246   (map) 
Drang  Nach  Osten,  352 
Dravidian  languages,  385,  387 
Dukhobars,  348 
Dulles,  J.  F.,  286 


East  Africa,  199 

East,  G.,  223,  226,  227,  400 

"East,"  Mackinder's  view  of,  256  ff. 

East  Pakistan,  as  exclave,  58,  62 

East  Prussia,  as  exclave,  58,  62 

Eastern  Europe,  225;  mass  migrations, 
356  ff.;  migrations  from,  350  ff. 

Eckermann,  J.  P.,  13 

Educational  factors,  441,  443 

"Effective  Occupation,"  83 

Egypt-Sudan,  boundary,   134 

Eire,  393  f.,  441 

Ellesmere  Island,  45  (map) 

Enclaves  and  Exclaves,  60  ff.;  in  metro- 
politan areas,  63 

English  language,  as  lingua  franca,  388 

Erie  Canal,  587 

Ethiopia,  expansion,  inland:  interior  loca- 
tion, 182;  landlocked  position,  182 

Europe,  see  Western  Europe 

European,  Coal  and  Steel  community, 
558 

European  countries,  population,  297,  299 

European:  expansion  overseas,  313;  eco- 
nomic co-operation,  organization  for 
(OEEC),  535  f.;  Payments  Union 
(EPU),  557 

Expansion:  ideological  justification  of, 
137  f. 


Fawcett,  C.  B.,  260 

Ferry,  J.,  533 

Feudal  states,  size  of,  30  ff. 

Fictitious  boundaries,  81,  82 

Finland:  as  buffer  state,  158;  settlement 
of  Karelian  Finns,  362 

Fissionable  materials,  see  Atoms  for 
Peace 

Floating  ice  islands,  250 

Foreign  trade:  China,  507,  514  f.;  im- 
portance to  Western  Europe,  549  ff.; 
intra-European  trade,  551;  Japan, 
527  f.;  Soviet  bloc,  488  f.;  U.S.S.R., 
485  ff. 

Formosa,  202,  231;  defense  resolution 
1955,  285 

Formosa  Strait,  285 

"Forward  Point  of  Growth,"  73  ff. 


France:  and  Catholicism,  419;  the  chaus- 
sees  of,  158;  demographic  factors,  314; 
depopulation  of  rural  areas,  131;  factor 
of  shape,  71;  overseas  immigration, 
369;  post  roads,  159  (map);  religious 
adherence,  407;  as  secular  state,  427; 
comparative  size,  42   (map) 

Frankfurt  a.M.,  157 

Free  World,  sea  communications,  228 

French  Canada,  390 

Frontier:  vs.  interior,  115;  psychology, 
116;  as  undelimited  border,  115 

Fulton,  R.,  587 


Gandhi,  M.,  434 

Garay,  Don  Juan  de,  152 

Gdynia,  77,  239 

General  Agreement  on  Tariff  and  Trade 
(GATT),  557 

Geographical:  determinism,  463  ff.;  fac- 
tors in  economic  development,  457  ff . 

Geopolitics,  5  ff. 

George,  H.  B.,  21 

German  internal  boundaries,  95 

Germany:  boundaries,  108  (map);  capi- 
tals, 156,  157;  Catholic  party  in,  436; 
communication  pattern,  161;  core 
areas,  156  f.;  demographic  factors, 
314  f.;  in  relation  to  Russia,  214;  lan- 
guage divisions,  402  f.;  language  fac- 
tors, 395,  396;  migration,  361  f.;  rival 
core  areas,  156 

Gezira  Scheme,  African  agriculture,  710 

Gibraltar,  Straits  of,  L90,  191 

Goethe,  J.  W.,  13  f. 

Gourou,  P.,  692 

Great  Britain  as  "Christian  power,"  427 

Great  Circle  Routes   ( across  Arctic ) ,  247 

Great  Lakes,  187 

Greek  colonization,  and  geography  of  lan- 
guages, 401 

Greenland,  45  (map),  250,  251,  253,  265 
(map),  277 

Greenland-Iceland  Bridge,  220 


Hansen,  M.  L.,  350 
Hapsburg  Empire,  139  (map) 
Harbors,  191 
Harris,  C,  484 
Harrison,  R.  E.,  43 
Haushofer,  K.,  7,  11,  26,  27,  76,  136 
Hawaiian  Islands,  66 
Heartland,  175,  208  ff.,  216  (map),  220 
(map),    224;    and    China,    221;    and 


INDEX 


717 


Eastern  Europe,  224  ff.;  interrelation- 
ship of,  and  marginal  lands,  227;  rain- 
fall, 223;  urge  to  the  sea,  243 

Hindu  sects  in  India,  411 

Hinduism,  differences  in,  411 

Historical  geography  and  distribution  of 
religions,  20  ff.,  405  f. 

Hoeffding,  O.,  494 

Hohenzollern,  acquisition  of  territory, 
64  f. 

Hokkaido,  231 

Hongkong,  221,  502 

Hoover,  H.,  272 

Human  Geography,  3  ff . 

Huntington,  E.,  440,  461,  568 

Hydroelectric  power,  466,  467;  China, 
501;  Japan,  525;  U.S.S.R.,  477,  479; 
Western  Europe,  540 


Ibn  Saud,  King,  205 

Iceland,  440  f.;  and  Western  Hemisphere, 
262  ff.,  265  (map);  factors  of  literacy, 
440  f. 

Ideological  groupings,  140  f. 

Imperialism:  of  European  powers,  532  ff.; 
Japanese,  522;  Soviet,  492  ff. 

India:   as  secular  state,   429;   boundaries 
of  princely   states,    134;   capitals,    151 
core   areas,   302;    Europe,   43    (map) 
geography  of  languages,  385  ff.,  389  f. 
industry,  657;  irrigation,  661;  linguistic 
states,    386    (map);    mass    migrations, 
363  f.;  mineral  resources,  653;  political 
divisions,    62;    populations,    297,    328 
(map);  population  distribution,  301  f.; 
textile  exports,  616 

Indian  Independence  Act  of  1947,  644 

Indian  Ocean,  British  influence,  68 
(map) 

Indians  overseas,  381  f. 

Indonesia,  a  circum-marine  state,  69,  70 
(map) 

Industrial  revolution,  469  f . 

Industry:  China,  505  ff.;  Japan,  527  f.; 
U.S.S.R.,  480,  483;  Western  Europe, 
543  f. 

Inland  waterways:  Europe,  544  f.; 
U.S.S.R.,  473 

"Inner  line"  of  communications,  175 

Intangible  power  factors,  441  f. 

Inter-American  highway,  261 

Interior  areas,  142 

International  agreements  and  U.S.  de- 
fense system,  281  ff. 

International  Bank  for  Reconstruction 
and  Development,  621 


International  Date  Line,  103  f. 

International  rivers,  184 

Iran,  oil,  207,  209;  railroads,  284  (map); 
Shiite  religion,  411 

Iraq,  oil,  630 

Irish:   Catholicism,  432 

"Iron  Curtain,"  85 

Iron  ore  and  coal:  China  and  Manchuria, 
500,  501;  importance  to  economic  de- 
velopment, 465,  466;  Japan,  524; 
U.S.S.R.,  477,  481  ff.;  Western  Europe, 
539,  542,  543 

irredentism,  396 

Irrigation,  464  f.;  China,  503  f.;  U.S.S.R., 
491 

Islam,  423  ff.,  424  (map),  426  (map) 

Island  chains,   198 

Island  refuge  areas,  200  ff. 

Island  states,  66 

Israel:  a  secular  state,  428;  Palestine- 
Syria  corridor,  192  (map);  core  area, 
147  (map);  immigration,  370  f.;  in- 
dustry, 636;  urban  drift,  371 

Istanbul,  144,  145 

Isthmus  of  Panama,  194,  195 

Italy:  communication  pattern,  163;  core 
areas  and  capitals,  146;  geography  of 
dialects,  403;  irredentism,  396;  popu- 
lation pressure,  353 


Japan:  agriculture,  526;  birth  rates, 
320  f.;  climate,  523;  comparison  with 
China,  519  ff.;  core  area,  155  f.;  eco- 
nomic development,  520  f.;  demo- 
graphic factors,  300  f.,  320  f.,  523  f.; 
economy,  519  ff.;  factor  of  compact- 
ness, 67;  fisheries,  526;  foreign  trade 
and  payments,  527  f.;  general  features 
of  the  economy,  525  ff.;  gross  national 
product,  521;  growth  of  military 
power,  522;  imperial  expansion,  522; 
imports  and  exports,  527  ff.;  industriali- 
zation, 525  ff.;  land  and  people,  523  f.; 
natural  resources,  524  f.;  overpopula- 
tion, 33.'>;  population,  328  (map); 
prospects,  529  f.;  Sea  of  Japan,  236 
(map);  security  agreement  with  U.S., 
283;  shift  of  capitals,  155  f.;  trade 
with  China,  615 

Jefferson,  Th.,  307 

Jerusalem:  as  capital,  146  ff.;  interna- 
tionalization, 419 

Jones,  S.  B.,  272 

Jordan  Valley  Project,  629,  634  f. 

Judaism,  distribution  of,  420  (map) 

Jungbluth,  62 


718 


INDEX 


Jus  Sanguinis,  nationality  law  of  China, 
380 


Kaganovitch,  L.,  485 

Kaliningrad,  239 

Kamchatka,  231 

Kashmir,  as  "Forward  Point  of  Growth, 

74 
Kazakhstan,  "Conquest  of  Virgin  Lands, 

490  f. 
Kenya,  Mau  Mau  uprising,  708  f. 
Keflavik,  262 
Khabarovsk,  221 
Khyber  Pass,  191 
Kiel  Canal,  197,  239 
Kitimat,  B.  C,  596 
Kra  Canal  Project,  196  f. 
Kurile  Islands,  231 
Kutznets,  S.,  602 
Kuwait,  oil,  630 


Labor  reserve,  330 

Landlocked  location,  175  f. 

Land  Reform  Program,  African  agricul- 
ture, 709  f. 

Languages:  as  barrier,  389  f.;  as  factor 
of  unification,  384  f.;  geography  of, 
383  ff. 

La  Plata,  drainage  basin,  268 

Latin  America:  agrarian  reform  pro- 
grams, 684  f.;  agricultural  land,  671  ff.; 
Amazon  Valley,  673;  area,  666  f.;  basic 
economic  characteristics,  678  f.;  cli- 
mate, 668  f.;  core  areas,  149;  depend- 
ency on  exports,  679  f.;  economic  im- 
portance (foreign  trade),  676  ff.; 
European  native  amalgamation,  347; 
foreign  investments,  677  f.;  future  eco- 
nomic prospect,  686  ff.;  future  popula- 
tion, 325;  geography,  668  ff.;  income, 
678  f.;  industrial  development,  681  ff.; 
meeting  of  Tegucigalpa,  682;  minerals, 

675  f.;  population,  666  f.;  racial  diver- 
sity, 668  f.;  racial  structure,  268  f.;  re- 
sources,   671  ff.;    strategic    importance, 

676  ff.;  system  of  land  tenure,  683  ff.; 
transportation,  680  f . 

Latin,  spread  of  language,  401 

Lattimore,  O.,  50 

Lebensraum,  26 

Legal    systems    in    political    geography, 

443  ff. 
Lena  River,   215 
"Lenaland,"  215 
Lenin,  I.,  227 


Leningrad,  239,  241 

Lingua  Franca:  in  China,  403;  in  India, 
368 

Linguistic:  islands,  348,  393  ff.;  pockets, 
396  ff.;  vs.  national  states,  139 

Literacy,  440 

Llivia,  Spanish  exclave,  61 

Location:  backdoor  areas,  180  ff.;  bound- 
aries, 176;  buffer  locations,  176  ff.; 
continental  seacoasts,  198  ff.;  cultural 
factors,  207  f.;  deserts,  204  f.;  harbors, 
191;  island  chains  and  land  bridges, 
198;  island  coasts,  200;  isthmuses,  194; 
landlocked  areas,  175  f.;  large  and 
small  countries,  206  f.;  narrow  con- 
tinental passages,  191  ff.;  narrow  ma- 
rine straits,  190  f.;  national  security 
and  locations,  189;  pass  areas,  191  ff.; 
peninsulas,  197  f.;  refuge  areas,  200  ff.; 
sea  power  position,  188 

Lodge,  H.  C,  11 

Lombok  Strait,  223 

Louisiana  extension,  98  (map) 


Mackinder,  H.  J.,  7,  14,  208,  211,  212, 
213,  214,  215,  217,  218,  219,  221,  222, 
223,  224,  225,  256  ff.,  343  f.,  449,  451, 
485,  531 

Madrid,  core  area,  153 

Mahan,  A.  T.,  11,  211,  212,  213 

Malaya:  Chinese  in,  378  (map);  immi- 
gration, 379  f . 

Manchuria,  499,  505,  506,  510  f. 

Manchurian  railways,  .19,  502 

Manifest  Destiny  in  Argentina,  10  ff., 
212,  313 

Manpower  factors,  327  ff. 

Maps,  spatial  misconceptions  due  to, 
41  ff. 

"March"  as  frontier  district,  116 

Marches,  U.S.  defense,  273  f. 

Marginal  lands,  see  Rimlands 

Marginal  seas,  227  ff. 

Marine  Straits,   190 

Marshall  Plan,  559,  565 

Marx,  K.,  307 

Matsu,  285 

Mau-Mau,  433,  708  f. 

Mecca,  as  core,  146 

Mediterranean,  240  (map),  241 

Mercator  projection,  217,  249,  295 

Metropolises,  vulnerability  of,  308  f. 

Metropolitan  areas,  37 

Mexico:  and  Catholicism,  419;  and  U.S.: 
Migratory  labor  problems,  377 

Middle  East,  oil  fields,  628  (map) 


INDEX 


719 


Middle  West,  core  of,  21  ff.,  115  f.,  142 

Migrations,  342  ff.;  directions  of  migra- 
tory pressure  in  Europe,  351  ff.;  of 
ethnic  Germans,  360  (map);  forced 
migrations,  355  f.;  laws  and  patterns  of, 
343  f.;  and  population  pressure,  345  f.; 
overseas,  368  (map);  postwar  migra- 
tion, 367  ff . 

Military  capabilities,  453,  455  ff. 

Millet,  65 

Mineral  resources,  465  ff.;  China,  500  f.; 
Japan,  524;  relation  to  economic  de- 
velopment, 467  f.;  U.S.S.R.,  475  ff.; 
Western  Europe,  539  ff. 

Minnesota-Canada  boundary,  92  (map) 

Minorities,  Europeans  in  Africa,  347 

Mishustin,  486 

Mississippi  River,  587,  588 

Mohawk  Valley,  193 

Mongol  empire,  213,  226 

Monroe  Doctrine,  258,  269  ff. 

Monsoon,  459  f.;  China,  496;  Japan, 
523  f.;  Asia,  334  f :  consumption  levels 
in,  334  f.,  646  f.;  population  pressure, 
332  ff.;  recent  population  growth, 
336  ff. 

Moslem  religion  and  population  distribu- 
tion, 306 

Mountain  refuge  areas,  202  f. 

Mozambique,  60,  75 


Narrow:  channels,  234  ff.;  waterways, 
227  ff. 

National:  Council  of  Churches  of  Christ, 
409;  socialism,  German  irredentism  of, 
396 

Nationalism  and  shape  of  state  terri- 
tories, 65  f . 

North  Atlantic  Treaty  Organization,  281, 
282  f.,  536,  565;  in  the  Baltic  area, 
239,  240;  strategic  position  in  Arctic, 
251 

Nehru,  J.,  381,  387 

Neo-mercantilism,  556 

Netherlands,  location,  206  f. 

Neutral  zones,  88 

New  Delhi  as  capital,  188,  151 

Newfoundland,  441 

Newspaper  circulation,  442  (map) 

New  York  City,  Puerto  Rican  immigra- 
tion, 377 

New  Zealand:  immigration  policy,  375; 
in  the  Antarctic,  246 

Nixon,  R.  M.,   171 

Nomadism,  28,  205 


Non-geographical  factors  ( in  economic 
development),   467  ff. 

North  America,  Eastern  population  dis- 
tribution, 303  f. 

North  German  plain,  194 

Northern  Sea  Route,  251 

"Northern  Tier,"  286  f. 

Northwest  Passage,  251 

Norway:  contiguity  of  islands,  66;  elon- 
gated shape  of,  73 


Oceanic  boundaries,  100  ff. 

Odd-shape  relationship  between  states, 
73  ff. 

Ohio  River,  587 

Okhotsk,  Sea  of,  231 

Okinawa,  278,  279 

Organic  theory  of  states,  135  ff. 

Organization  for  European  Economic  Co- 
operation (OEEC),  535  f.,  554  f. 

Ormuz,  Straits  of,  234 

Osborn,  F.,  673 

Overseas  Areas,  313  f.;  settlement  of 
European,  346  ff. 

Overseas  territories,  European,  551 

Owen  Falls  Dam,  441 


Pacific  Area:  strategic  bases,  277  f.;  con- 
tinental shelf,  101 

Pakistan:  an  islamic  nation,  286  ff., 
428  f.;  and  Kashmir,  97;  economic 
problems,  644  ff.,  664;  geography  of 
languages,  388;  irrigation,  100;  non- 
contiguous state  area,  58  ff.,  59  ( map ) 

Palestine,  93,  127,  128 

Palestine-Syria  corridor,  192  f. 

Palmer  Peninsula,  245 

Panama:  Canal,  165,  187,  194  ff.,  234  f., 
237,  245;  Isthmus  of,  194;  Declara- 
tion of,  101 

Pan  American  Highway,  194,  261 

Pan  American  Security,  270  ff. 

Papal  State,  29 

Papua,  95 

Parallel,  38th  in  Korea,  34 

Paramushino,  231 

Parella,  F.,  11  ff. 

Pass  states,  190  ff. 

Pei,  M.,  402 

Peking,  153  f.,  157,  301 

Peninsulas,  197 

Perimeter  of  Defense,  253  ff.,  272  ff.,  275 
(map) 

Peru,  181  f.,  187 


720 


INDEX 


Pescadores  Islands,  74 

Petroleum:  importance  to  world  energy 
supply,  466  ff.;  Middle  East,  628 
(map);  principal  producing  areas,  467; 
U.S.S.R.,  477 

Petsamo,  77,  78 

Philby,  St.  J.  B.,  87,  430 

Pipelines:  Southeast  Asia,  211;  Saudi 
Arabia,  £11 

"Pivot  Area"  (Mackinder),  209  f.,  214, 
216 

Po  Valley,  194 

Poland  Boundaries,  81  f.,  82  (map),  156; 
on  the  Baltic  Sea,  77,  239;  Jewish 
minority,  359;  minorities,  359;  popula- 
tion pressure,  356  f. 

Polar  Aviation,  78 

Polar:  Ice  Pack,  79;  Mediterranean, 
220  ff.,  249;  Regions,  strategic  bases, 
87 

Political  Attitudes  and  the  map  of  re- 
ligion, 408 

Population:  factors,  294  ff.;  distribution, 
299  ff.;  dynamics  of,  99  ff.;  expansion 
of  Europe,  310  f.;  fertility  factors,  309; 
effects  of  war,  326;  growth,  309  ff.; 
intensive  use  of  the  home  territory, 
312;  national  entities,  92;  settlement  of 
the  East,  312;  outlook  for  next  decade, 
340;  settlement  of  overseas  areas, 
313  f.;  size  of,  295  ff.;  structure, 
327  ff.;   transfers,  356  ff. 

Population  pressure,  331  ff.,  341;  and 
migrations,  345  ff . 

Population  vs.  Area,  91  f. 

Population  growth:  outlook  age  pyramid, 
102;  age  structures,  102  f.;  future  pop- 
ulations, 323  ff. 

Population   growth   and   pressure,   91  ff. 

Population:  composition  factors,  102; 
pressure,  103  f.;  movement,  USA,  104; 
trends:  China,  158,  159,  165;  Japan, 
168;  U.S.S.R.,  150;  Western  Europe, 
179:   Porkkala-Udd,  71 

Portugal:  as  buffer,  179;  colonialism,  34, 
69,  91,  122,  176,  185,  35  (map);  sphere 
of  influence,  256;  religious  adherence, 
407  f. 

Possibilism,  4 

Presidential  elections,  political  geography 
of,   109 

Prestige  factor  in  boundary  changes, 
122  f. 

Problems  of  Economics,  151 

Productivity  of  labor:  in  agriculture,  181; 
China,  164;  Soviet  Agriculture,  156; 
U.S.S.R.,  153;  Western  Europe,  179 


"Prompted  Shape,"  73  f. 

Protestantism,  420   (map),  421  f. 

Pseudo-religious  ideologies,  140 

Psychological  factor  of  frontier  mentality, 
121 

Puerto  Rico  emigration,  130,  377 

Punjab,  language  factors,  387  f.;  migra- 
tions,   363  f. 

Pushtu  language,  90 

Pushtunistan,  394 


"Quarter-Sphere,"  American,  267 
Quebec,  390 
Quemoy,  285 


Racial  factor  in  political  geography,  383  f . 

Radiating  communications,  patterns  and 
core  areas,  52 

Radio  distribution  concept,  444 

Railroads,  51  f.,  53,  59;  as  outlets  for 
landlocked  countries,  58 

Railways,  167  ff.;  Central  Africa,  186; 
China,  502  f.;  U.S.S.R.,  159  ff.,  484  f.; 
Western  Europe,  159  ff.,  161;  South 
America,  161  f. 

Ratzel,  F.,  7,  27,  52,  95,  135,  136 

Raum,  see  Space 

Ravenstein,  E.  C,  343 

Reformation,  426 

Refuge  Areas,  200  ff. 

Regional  organizations,  38  ff. 

Religions,  political  geography  of,  405  ff., 
410  (map) 

Rhee  Line,  526 

Rhine  River  as  international  river,  184, 
538 

Ribbon  Developments,  189 

Rimlands,  223  ff.,  225  (map);  popula- 
tion density,  71;  strategic  vulner- 
ability, 72 

Rio  Grande,  97 

Rio  de  Janeiro  Treaty,  83,  85,  88,  271, 
281 

Ritter,  K.,  342 

River  basins,  99 

River  boundaries,  97  ff. 

Rivers,  internationalization  of,  184 

Roman  Catholic  countries,  406  ff.,  416 
(map),  417  ff.;  distinctions  between 
Spain,  Portugal,  France,  407  f . 

Roman  colonization  and  geography  of 
languages,  401 

Roman  Empire,  compactness  of,  22 

Rome,  capital  and  core,  146 

Roosevelt,  F.  D.,  262,  263,  270 


INDEX 


721 


Roosevelt,  Th.,  10 

Ross,  A.,  712 

Rub'al  Khali,  87,  88  (map),  204 

Ruhr,  Planning  Authority,  113,  159;  lin- 
guistic factors,  403 

Rumania,  autonomous  regions,  203 

Russia,  see  U.S.S.R. 

Russian  capitals,  148  ff. 

Russification  policy  of  U.S.S.R.,  141, 
398  f. 


Saar,  113  (map),  114,  118,  121 

Sahara,  47  f.,  204 

Sakhalin,  231 

Satellites:  boundaries,  133  (map);  eco- 
nomic factors  of  Soviet,  492  ff.;  inte- 
gration of,  494;  population  493;  trade, 
493 

Saudi  Arabia,  87  f.,  134  f.;  and  Wahha- 
bism,  430 

Scandinavian:  Airlines,  247  f.;  Customs 
Union,  558 

Schwarz,  S.  M.,  126 

Sea  Power  and  expansion  inland,  188; 
Mahan's  concept  of,  212 

Seacoasts  of  continents,  198  f. 

SEATO,  283  f. 

Sector  principle,  83  f.,  128  (map) 

Sedentary  ways  of  life,  205 

Semple,  E.  C,  27,  136 

Senussi,  430  f . 

Serbs,  Orthodox  Church,  431  f. 

Seward,  W.  H.,  4 

Shanghai,  153,  301 

Shape,  58  ff. 

Shaw,  G.  R.,  402 

Shintoism,  431 

Shipping  lanes  and  core  areas,   163  ff. 

Shoreline  as  boundary,  100 

Siberia,  Western  ("Conquest  of  Virgin 
Lands"),  156 

Siegfried,  A.,  24,  640 

Silesia,  239,  241 

Sikkim,  74  f .,  97 

Singapore,   190 

Sinkiang,  73,  158,  172,  499 

Sino-Soviet  Rloc,  economic  factors,  471  ff. 

Size,  26  ff.;  factors  in  internal  political 
geography,  52  ff.;  security,  44  ff.;  state 
power  and  factor  of,  30;  psychologi- 
cal factors  of,  50  ff.;  physiographic 
factors  of,  56  f . 

Slavic  expansion,   365  f . 

Slovaks,  minority  problems,  361 

Smith,  A.,  452 

Smith,  J.,  23 


Smuts,  J.  C,  16 

Soils  and  vegetation,  461  ff. 

South  Africa,  Union  of,  130  f.;  Apartheid, 
60  f.;  enclaves  in,  60;  European  minor- 
ity in,  347;  minority,  Indian,  381  f.; 
seat  of  government,  169;  political  ge- 
ography of  languages,  391;  religious, 
433 

South  America:  "Rackdoor"  areas,  181; 
boundaries,  89;  border  zones,  87;  and 
Canada,  259;  core  areas,  149  ff.;  re- 
sources, 674  (map) 

South  China  Sea,  232  (map) 

South  Moluccas,  202 

South  Pole,  245  f. 

South  and  Southeast  Asia:  agricultural 
land,  650  f.;  agriculture,  658  ff.;  area, 
644  f.;  coal,  653;  economic  characteris- 
tics, 654  ff.;  economic  significance, 
648  ff.;  exports,  655,  659;  industriali- 
zation, 657;  iron  ore,  653;  irrigation, 
661:  petroleum,  653;  physical  ge- 
ography and  climate,  646  f.;  popula- 
tion, 644;  power  vacuum,  643  f.;  pros- 
pects, 662  ff.;  resources  and  railroads, 
652  (map);  security  problems,  283, 
286;  strategic  significance,  648  ff.; 
tenancy,  661  f.;  transportation,  657  f.; 
water  power,  653;  water  supply,  660  f. 

Southern  Europe,  migrations  from,  353 

Southern  Manchurian  Railways,   19,  185 

"Southern  Union"  of  Argentina,  269 

"Southern  Union,"  Peron's,  84 

Southwest  Asia:  agricultural  land,  627  f.; 
agriculture,  632  ff.;  air  transport,  641; 
area  and  population,  625  f.;  exports, 
633;  geography  and  climate,  626;  in- 
dustry, 520  (map),  635  ff.;  irrigation, 
634;  minerals,  631  f.;  petroleum, 
629  ff.,  636  ff.;  railroads,  520  (map); 
resources,  626  ff.;  tenure,  635;  trans- 
portation,  639  ff. 

Space,  expansion  in,  26  ff. 

Spain:  and  Catholicism,  419;  core  area, 
153,  159;  geography  of  languages,  400, 
401;  population  pressure,  353;  re- 
ligious adherence,  407  f.;  strategic  po- 
sition, 282 

Spate,  O.  H.  K.,  115 

Spengler,  O.,  80,  95 

Spvkman,  N.  J.,  223,  228,  267,  268 

Stalev,  E.,  261 

State  capitals  in  U.S.,  49 

State  lines  in  U.S.,  34 

States,   increase   of   "independent,"   6 

Stefansson,  V.,  78,  82,  13,  245  f.,  263 

Stepinac,  Cardinal,  430,  341 


722 


INDEX 


Sterling  area,  551 

Straits,  see  Dardanelles 

Strategic  bases:  in  the  Arctic,  249  f.,  279; 
development  in  World  War  I  and 
II,  275  ff.;  structure  of,  278  f.;  termi- 
nology, 86;  U.S.  bases  overseas,  278  f. 

Strategic  Trusteeship  Area,  87 

St.  Croix  River,  90,  93,  97 

St.  Lawrence  River,   127 

St.  Lawrence  Seaway,  165  f.,  166  (map), 
187 

St.  Petersburg,   148,   159,   183 

Submarines,  role  in  Soviet  strategy,  253 

Subterranean  boundaries,  44 

Sudeten  Germans,  539  ff. 

Suez  Canal,  165,  190,  194  ff.,  241,  245, 
560,  639  f.,  700  f. 

Sunda  Strait,  74 

Sunnites,  411 

Swaziland,   130 

Sweden,  location  of  industries,  119  f., 
189,  239 

Switzerland,  30,  60,  61,  62,  64,  123,  138, 
169,  178,  191;  language  factors,  356, 
389 

Szczecin  (Stettin),  184,  239 


Ta  Chen,  297 

Taiga,  300 

Taiwan,  see  Formosa 

Tallinn,  239 

Tartary,  Strait  of,  235 

Taylor,  C,  131 

Teggart  Wall,  93 

Telugu  language,  387 

Toiassen  n,  75 

TVA  (Tennessee  Valley  /uthrity),  54, 
99  f.,  574  ( map ) 

Territorial  Aggrandizement,  40  f . 

Teutons  and  Slavs  in  Europe,  115  f. 

Thailand,   177  f. 

Thomas,  R.,  87 

Thule  Air  Rase,  251  ff. 

Tibet,  74,  97;  a  theocracy,  429  f. 

Tocqueville,  A.  de,  390 

Tokyo,  527 

Tordesillas,  Partition  of,  102,  254  (map), 
255  f. 

Toynbee,  A.  J.,  143,  148,  273 

Trade  areas  and  frontiers,  121 

Trading  posts,  extraterritorial  and  fac- 
tories, 22 

Trans-Iranian  Railroad,  167  f. 

Trevelyan,  G.  M.,  174,  469 

Trevor,  R.  H.,  9 

Trieste,  324 


Tundra,  300 

Turkey:  core,  144  (map);  industry,  209; 

mineral  resources,  631  f.;  "millet,"  65; 

railroads    of,    168,    984    (map);    shift 

of  capitals,  144,  157,  159 
Turksib  Railroad,  167 
Tyrol,  94,  384  f.,  397 


Ukraine,  40  f.,  41  (map),  171,  226,  239; 
language  factors,  384 

Ulan  Rator,  517 

Underdeveloped  Areas:  agriculture, 
603  ff.;  atoms-for-peace,  621  f.;  chal- 
lenge of  economic  backwardness, 
608  ff.;  Communist  penetration,  609  f., 
614  f.,  618  f.;  demographic  factors, 
607  f.;  diseases,  602  f.;  economic  char- 
acteristics, 601  ff.;  exports,  606  f.;  in- 
dustrialization, 616  ff.;  International 
Rank  for  Reconstruction  and  Develop- 
ment, 621;  Point  Four,  620  ff.;  poverty, 
602  f.;  productivity,  601  ff.;  strategic 
factors,   612  f.;   transportation,   605 

United  Kingdom:  shipping  lanes,  163  ff., 
164  (map);  demographic  factors, 
316  f.;  colonial  structure,  173;  emigra- 
tion, 375;  population  composition,  329 
(map) 

Ural-Caspian  Gate,  193 

Urban  concentration,  306 

Urban  drift,  354  f . 

Urbanization,  and  population  stability, 
306  ff. 

Urdu  language,  388    • 

Urumchi,  517 

"Urge  to  the  Sea,"  182  ff. 

U.S.A.:  agriculture  land,  573  f.;  agri- 
culture, 584  ff.;  boundary  with  Canada, 
114;  boundary  with  Mexico,  114,  129  f. 
(map);  boundary  disputes  between 
States,  106  (map);  communication 
pattern,  163;  continental  shelf,  101, 
124  f.;  core  areas  (California),  169  f.; 
expansion  inland,  188;  economic  capa- 
bilities, 567  ff.;  energy  resources, 
477  f.;  foreign  trade,  590  ff.;  forests, 
575;  geometrical  boundaries,  104  f.; 
geography,  people,  568  ff.;  gross  na- 
tional product,  580;  language  factors, 
139;  manufactures,  582  f.;  minerals, 
575  ff.;  movement  of  people,  188, 
571  f.;  population,  473,  570  ff.;  pros- 
pects, 574  (map),  587  f.;  religions, 
409;  resources,  523;  sector  principle, 
85;  size,  comparative,  44  (map);  state 
boundaries,    86;    state    capitals,    151; 


INDEX 


723 


transportation,  586  f.;  urban  drift,  354, 
572;  U.S.S.R.  boundary,  102  f.;  water 
power,  579,  f.;  waterways,  588  ff.; 
westward  movement,  572  (map) 
U.S.S.R.:  administrative  subdivisions,  54; 
agriculture,  489  f.;  arable  land,  473  f.; 
in  the  Arctic,  182  ff.;  atheistic  state, 
autonomy  principle,  66;  backdoor 
areas,  180;  in  the  Baltic  Sea,  237  ff.; 
blockade,  geographical,  242  ff.;  capi- 
tals, 148  ff.;  central  position,  514  ff.; 
coal  production,  472,  479;  demo- 
graphic factors,  315  f.,  320;  depend- 
encies, 172;  eastward  movement,  312; 
economic  prospects,  483  ff.;  economy 
and  capabilities,  480  ff.,  489  ff.;  energy 
resources,  477  f.;  expansion  of  econ- 
omy, 480  ff.,  489  ff.;  foreign  trade, 
485  ff.;  grain  production,  in  Soviet 
Asia,  491;  inland  waterways,  473;  irri- 
gation projects,  473,  491;  Islam,  and, 
425;  labor  force,  475;  location  theory, 
485;  migrations  and  population  trans- 
fers, 342  f.,  349  ff.,  491;  minerals,  re- 
serves, imports  and  exports,  475  ff., 
479  f.;  natural  resources,  475  ff.;  naval 
power,  242  ff.;  petroleum,  477;  physi- 
cal features,  473,  484;  population 
growth  and  structure,  315  f.,  329  f., 
474  f.;  railroads,  222,  476  (map),  478 
(map);  reclamation  of  new  land,  490; 
relocation  of  industries,  189;  religions, 
distribution  of,  480  f.;  rivers,  183,  473; 
size,  comparative,  44  (map);  trans- 
portation system,  484  f.;  urban  drift, 
354;  urge  to  the  sea,  182  ff.;  U.S.A. 
boundary,  102  f.;  "virgin  lands  con- 
quest," 490;  waterways,  473;  water- 
power,  477 


'conquest"      of 


in 


Vegetation,   461  ff. 
"Virgin      Lands": 

U.S.S.R.,  490 
Virginia,  Commonwealth  of,  63 
"Vital  Revolution,"  318  ff. 
Vladivostok,  235 


Wachstumsspitze,  see  Forward  Point  of 

Growth 
Wahhabism,   430 

War,  effects  on  future  populations,  326 
Washington,  D.C.,  as  core,  145  f.,  169 
Water  bodies,  260  ( map ) 


Weather  observation  stations  in  Arctic, 
250  f . 

Wei  Valley,  153 

Western  Europe:  agriculture,  547  f.,  560; 
climatic  factors,  537  f.;  colonialism, 
532  f.;  coal  production,  559  f.;  cultural 
factors,  534;  economic  capabilities, 
531  ff.;  economic  structure,  541  ff.; 
energy  and  fuel  supply,  542  f.,  559; 
expansion,  531  f.;  European  Coal  and 
Steel  Community,  558;  foreign  trade, 
549  ff.;  geographical  features,  535  f.; 
gross  national  product,  541;  industry 
and  manufacturing,  543  f.;  interna- 
tional economic  organizations,  535  f.; 
integration,  steps  toward,  557  f.;  man- 
power and  productivity,  553  ff.; 
Marshall  Plan,  565;  payments  prob- 
lems, 563  f.;  present  position  in  world 
economy,  552  ff.;  population  growth, 
532;  Organization  for  European  Eco- 
nomic Cooperation  (OEEC),  535  f., 
554  f.,  557,  560;  railroads,  540  (map), 
546  f.;  regional  patterns,  548  f.;  re- 
sources 538  ff.,  540  (map);  Scandi- 
navian customs  union,  558;  sterling 
area,  551;  westward  thrust  in,  365  ff.; 
transportation,  544  f.;  waterways, 
544  f.;  world  trade,  decline  of  Western 
Europe's  share,  562  f . 

Western  Hemisphere,  253  ff.,  264  (map) 

Western  Reserve,  64 

Western  Security  System,  280  (map) 

"Westward  Course  of  Empire,"  349,  572 
(map) 

"Wetbacks,"  129  f.,  377 

White  Sea,  237  f. 

White  Sea-Baltic  Canal,  161 

Wigmore,  J.  F.,  443 

World,  demographic  regions,  322   (map) 

World,   relative   land   areas,    294    (map) 

World,  population  growth,  323  (map), 
324  (map) 

World  state,  28  f. 

Wright,  J.  K.,  535 

Wright,  Q.,  25 


Yangtse  Valley,  153,  496  f.,  501  f. 

Yedo,  156 

Yenisei  River,  218 

Yugoslavia:      backdoor      location,      182; 

boundaries,   93;   churches,  430,  435  f.; 

nationalities,    392;    political   geography 

of  languages,  392 


Due 

COLLEGE  LIBRARY 

Date  Due 
Returned             Due 

Returned 

JUhf  *  n 

_JUN  0  5 1997 

*    o    {f 

897 

• 

3>S»3f21#J 


8  8ZJ9  BIMT1 


1 


13MOOd  MOOS  OX 

auvo  Nunigu  (z 


CO 

ro 

r*"l 


-P. 

:— a. 

■•jO 


ONE  WORLD 
DIVIDED 


1956 


_c3 


& 


GREENLAND 


AM 


i'CEUNDJ 


S> 


<r 


4- 


*> 


/ 


* 


II 


tux?. 

/  J 

CHANCE  ./Mm 


PORTUGAL 


/ 

/?      SPAIN 


v. 


<J 


MOROCCO 


3 


/ 

(tunisia 

\    • 

ALGERIA         V     A 


Neutralist  Notions  and  Notions  Not  Participating  in  Western  Defense  Pacts 


Principles  of  political  geogra  main 
320.1W419pC2 


-.0* 


DUHO 


|pps* 


*.-— w^- 


\ 


#^#t*  RUMAMIA> 

ALBANtAV-S* 


3  15b2  03ESS  3SQM        JHE    NORTHERN 

HEMISPHERE 


$ 


&£££§§  ? 


VStV  •.':•:•.;:■::•:      CO      J  :*>.£ 


<£ 


pYRlA^ 


terronean 


£s       HSy&V  rvKUWAI 

lEBANON^.:^,^.^,^,^...^^.^ 


The  "West":  NATO  and  Baghdad  Pact  Nations 


U.S.S.R.,  China,  and  Satellite  Nations