Skip to main content

Full text of "Regression tests of the present value model and speculative bubbles"

See other formats


Faculty  Working  Paper  91-0150 


330  STX 

B385 

1991:150   COPY   2 


Regression  Tests  of  the  Present  Value 
Model  and  Speculative  Bubbles 


1  2  1991 


Yoon  Dokko 

Department  of  Finance 


Bureau  of  Economic  and  Business  Research 

College  of  Commerce  and  Business  Administration 

University  of  Illinois  at  Urbana-Champaign 


BEBR 


FACULTY  WORKING  PAPER  NO.  91-0150 

College  of  Commerce  and  Business  Administration 

University  of  Illinois  at  Urbana-Champaign 

June  1991 


Regression  Tests  of  the  Present  Value 
Model  and  Speculative  Bubbles 


Yoon  Dokko,  Assistant  Professor 
Department  of  Finance 


1  would  like  to  thank  Robert  Shiller  for  the  data  base  and  James  Davis  and  Louis  Scott 
for  comments.   I  am  responsible  for  any  remaining  errors. 


Abstract 

This  paper  develops  a  regression  test  of  the  present  value  model,  which 
holds  regardless  of  whether  rational  bubbles  are  present  in  stock  prices.  We 
test  whether  the  forecast  error  of  the  stock  price  with  respect  to  the  ex  post 
rational  price  is  consistent  with  the  present  value  model.  The  statistical 
results  cannot  reject  the  null  hypothesis. 


Digitized  by  the  Internet  Archive 

in  2011  with  funding  from 

University  of  Illinois  Urbana-Champaign 


http://www.archive.org/details/regressiontestso91150dokk 


Introduction 

The  objective  of  this  paper  is  two-fold.  First,  this  paper  demonstrates  that 
the  failure  of  some  regression  tests  to  accept  the  present  value  model  cannot 
be  attributed  to  the  existence  of  rational  speculative  bubbles.  Second,  the 
paper  proposes  an  alternative  regression  test  of  the  present  value  model 
that  is  valid  regardless  of  whether  rational  bubbles  are  present  in  stock 
prices. 

One  may  suppose  that  the  stock  price  can  be  decomposed  into  a  fun- 
damental value  and  a  rational  bubble  and  that  the  fundamental  value  is 
determined  by  the  present  value  model: 

Pt    =    Ft  +  Bt 

where  Pt  is  the  stock  price  at  the  beginning  of  period  t  +  1  (or  at  time  tf), 
Ft  is  the  fundamental  value  at  time  t,  Bt  is  the  bubble  at  time  t,  Dt+i  is 
the  dividend  paid  during  period  t  +  i  (or  from  time  t  +  i :  —  1  through  time 
t  +  i),  k  is  the  discount  rate,  which  is  assumed  to  be  constant,  and  Et  is  the 
investor's  expectations  operator  conditional  upon  information  available  at 
time  t.  Flood  and  Garber  (1980)  show  that  when  bubbles  satisfy  the  Euler 
equation,1  i.e.,  when  bubbles  are  rational,  we  have 

Bt   =   YT~kEtBt+l'  ^ 

Following  LeRoy  and  Porter  (1981)  and  Shiller  (1981),  we  define  the 


lrThe  Euler  equation  is  the  first-order  condition  for  a  representative  consumer's  lifetime 
expected  utility  maximization. 


"ei  post  rational"  price,  P*,  as 

p<-  =  SoW  (3) 

Since  EtP*  =  Fu  we  have 

p;  =  pt-jft  +  ^  (4) 

where  r)t  is  a  rational  forecast  error,  in  that  it  is  uncorrelated  with  Pt  and 
Bt.  In  the  absence  of  bubbles  (i.e.,  Bt  —  0),  we  have 

p;  =  Pt  +  m  (5) 

and 

var(P;)    >    var(Pt).  (6) 

The  failure  of  the  statistical  results  of  various  studies  to  accept  inequal- 
ity condition  (6)  has  ignited  heated  debates  among  researchers.  Some  re- 
searchers suggest  that  the  failure  of  variance  bounds  tests  to  accept  the 
present  value  model  can  be  attributed  to  the  existence  of  speculative  bub- 
bles. However,  Flood  and  Hodrick  (1986)  demonstrate  that  most  variance 
bounds  tests  preclude  bubbles  as  an  explanation.  Others  doubt,  for  various 
reasons,  the  usefulness  of  variance  bounds  tests.  For  example,  Marsh  and 
Merton  (1986)  suggest  that  since  stock  prices  are  non-stationary,  imposing 
an  upper  bound  on  stock  price  volatility  is  not  meaningful  for  testing  the 
present  value  model. 

From  these  debates,  an  alternative  approach  for  testing  the  present  value 
model  has  emerged.  Scott  (1985)  suggests  that  ordinary  least  squares  (OLS) 


regression  tests  of  equation  (7)  are  more  powerful  than  variance  bounds 
tests:2 

P;     =    a  +  bPt  +  r,t  (7) 

where  trends  are  removed  from  the  data,  and  a  =  0  and  6  =  1  under  the 
null  hypothesis. 

Scott  suggests  that  the  existence  of  bubbles  could  cause  his  regression 
test  to  reject  the  present  value  model.  As  will  be  shown  later,  Scott's  fail- 
ure to  accept  the  null  hypothesis  cannot  be  attributed  to  the  existence  of 
rational  bubbles.  Also,  application  of  OLS  to  equation  (7)  yields  ineffi- 
cient coefficient  estimates  because  the  rational  forecast  error  rjt  is  serially 
correlated.  To  show  this,  we  utilize  the  definition  of  P*  such  that 

p*     _     Pjt+i  +  A+i  ,Qs 

Pt    ~       T+i     '  (8) 

From  equations  (1)  and  (2),  we  describe  the  stock  price  as 

_    £7,(Pt+1  +  A+i)  ,Q, 

Let 

Pm  +  A+i   =  £*CP*+i  +  A+i)  +  ^+i  (10) 

where  \xt  is,  by  definition,  a  rational  forecast  error,  which  is  serially  uncor- 
related.  Equation  (9)  becomes 

Pt  -       m      •  (11) 

Subtracting  equation  (11)  from  equation  (8)  yields 

*-*   =   TTk^  ~  Pl+')  +  TTk"^  (12) 

2See  alsoShiller  (1990). 


In  the  absence  of  bubbles,  rjt  =  P*  —  Pt,  and  rjt  is  the  present  value  of  future 
forecast  errors  (i.e.,  HSi  <i+k)<  )•  OLS  estimation  of  equation  (7)  thus  yields 
inefficient  coefficient  estimates  under  the  null  hypothesis. 

Applying  generalized  least  squares  (GLS)  or  maximum  likelihood  es- 
timation (MLE)  to  equation  (5)  is  equivalent  to  estimating  (note  that 
Dt  =  (1  +  k)P;_x  -  P;)  equation  (13): 

Pt    =    (l  +  A:)Pt-i-A  +  /it.  (13) 

Chow  (1989)  finds  that  the  data  are  not  consistent  with  equation  (13). 
However,  Dokko  (1991)  suggests  that  without  a  theory  of  why  and  how 
dividends  are  paid,  one  may  not  test  the  present  value  model  in  the  form  of 
equation  (13)  using  the  observed  stock  price-dividend  relation.  For  exam- 
ple, as  discussed  in  Dokko,  if  we  incorporate  the  informational  effect  of  the 
dividend  and  dividend  smoothing  behavior  into  the  present  value  model,  we 
see  that  the  relationships  of  the  current  stock  price  with  the  lagged  stock 
price  and  the  current  dividend  are  determined  by  several  forces,  such  as  the 
capitalization  of  an  unexpected  dividend,  the  dividend  smoothing  policy, 
and  the  discount  rate. 

We  may  summarize  the  problems  with  testing  the  present  value  model 
in  the  following  ways:  First,  the  variance  bounds  test  may  not  be  useful  if 
the  stock  price  is  non-stationary.  Second,  OLS  estimation  of  equation  (7) 
is  inefficient  since  the  rational  forecast  error  rft  is  serially  correlated  under 
the  null  hypothesis.  This  inefficiency  will  be  exacerbated  by  measurement 
errors  in  the  estimated  P*.  Finally,  without  a  theory  of  dividends,  it  would 
be  difficult  to  be  sure  that  the  observed  stock  price-dividend  relation  is 
capable  of  testing  the  present  value  model,  as  opposed  to  inadvertently 

4 


estimating  another  relation. 

The  rest  of  the  paper  is  organized  as  follows:  Section  I  proves  that  the 
Scott-type  regression  tests  of  the  present  value  model  cannot  detect  the 
existence  of  rational  bubbles.  Section  II  presents  an  alternative  regression 
test.  Our  approach  does  not  require  a  theory  of  dividends,  and  the  statisti- 
cal results  are  valid  regardless  of  whether  speculative  bubbles  are  present. 
We  find  that  the  data  appear  to  be  consistent  with  the  present  value  model. 
Section  III  contains  a  brief  conclusion. 

I.     On  Testing  for  Rational  Bubbles 

Since  P*  is  not  observed,  researchers  usually  assume  that  the  observed 
market  price  at  the  end  of  the  sample  period,  Pj,  is  the  same  as  the  ex  post 
perfect  foresight  price  at  that  time,  Pf.  The  estimated  ex  post  rational 
price  P*  is  obtained  in  the  following  way: 

P*     =     PT  =  p*  +  BT-  rjT 
Pt-i    =    Y^(^t  +  DT)  =  Pr_,  +  ^(Br  -  riT) 

Using  P*  and  Pt,  the  least  squares  estimate  b  in  regression  (7),  with  the 
null  hypothesis  of  b  =  1,  is 


b    =     cov(p;,Pt)/var(Pt) 


=      C°V  (^  +  (l+\)T-t(BT  -  *»•)'  Pt)  /Var^^ 


=    cov 


U  -Bt+      +  \        Br,  Pt)  /varfP,)-  (15) 


The  last  equality  holds  because  cov(r)t,  Pt)  =  cov(tjt,  Pt)  =  0.  Since  bubbles 
evolve  over  time,  the  bubble  at  time  T  (Bt)  is  correlated  with  the  bubble 
at  time  t  (Bt,  t  <  T)  and  thus  with  Pt.  In  other  words,  we  can  express  Bt 
as 

BT    =    (1  +  fc)#r-i  +  eT 

=    (l  +  A:)2BT_2  +  (l  +  A:)eT_1  +  eT 

=    (\  +  k)T-tBt  +  (l  +  k)T-t-let+l  +  --  +  eT  (16) 

where  et  is,  by  definition,  white  noise  and  uncorrelated  with  information 
available  at  time  t.  Since  cov(et+t,  Pt)  =  0  for  all  i  >  1,  it  follows  that 

b    =    1  (17) 

This  proves  that  failure  to  accept  the  null  hypothesis  of  6  =  1  in  regression 
(7),  using  P*  and  Pt,  cannot  be  attributed  to  the  presence  of  rational 
bubbles. 

II.  An  Alternative  Regression  Test  of  the  Present  Value  Model 

A.  Methodology 

The  empirical  analysis  will  be  directed  to  examining  whether  the  present 
value  relation  in  equation  (12)  holds.  The  test  of  the  present  value  model  in 
the  form  of  equation  (12)  has  several  advantages  over  the  test  of  the  present 
value  model  in  the  form  of  P*  =  Pt  +  r]t.  First,  as  Flood  and  Hodrick  (1986) 

6 


warned,  model  specification  for  testing  rational  bubbles,  using  ex  post  data, 
is  not  an  easy  task.  It  is  desirable  to  develop  a  model,  such  as  equation  (12), 
which  holds  irrespective  of  the  presence  of  rational  bubbles.  Second,  since 
fit  is  serially  uncorrelated  under  the  null  hypothesis,  OLS  estimation  of 
equation  (12)  is  efficient.  Third,  even  though  P*  is  unobserved,  estimation 
of  equation  (12)  is  robust  with  respect  to  measurement  errors  in  P* .  This 
can  be  seen  as  follows: 

=  rb(i7+»  -  p^ + IT***1 + (i +fcr-'(i?r "  ^ 

(18-a) 

P;+1-Pt+1    =    P;+1  -  Pt+i  +  (1  +  klTHt+1)  (BT  -  iyr).  (18-b) 

Substituting  Ptm+l  -  Pt+1  -  {1+k)}-it+x)(BT  -  r]T)  for  Pt*+l  -  Pt+l  in  equation 
(18-a)  yields 

p'-p'  =   lhiP^-p^)  +  TTk^-  (19) 

We  use  equation  (19)  to  test  the  present  value  model. 

B.  The  Data  Base 

The  data  base  is  the  same  as  that  used  in  Campbell  and  Shiller  (1987).  Pt 
is  the  stock  price  for  January  of  each  year  t  -f-  1  from  1872  through  1987, 
deflated  by  the  price  deflator  for  January  of  that  year.  Dt  is  the  dividend  for 
each  year  t  from  1872  through  1986,  deflated  by  the  average  price  deflator 
for  the  corresponding  year.3    The  assumed  discount  rate  is  8.35%,  which 


3If  Pt  is  the  stock  price  for  January  1987,  the  corresponding  Dt  is  the  dividend  paid 
during  the  year  of  1986. 


is  the  average  annual  real  rate  of  return  on  common  stocks  for  the  sample 
period. 

C.  Statistical  Results 

If  P*  —  Pt  is  stationary,  the  testing  equation  is 

p;-pt  =  A  +  A(p;+1-pt+1)  (20) 

where  /?'s  are  regression  coefficients  to  be  estimated,  and  the  null  hypothesis 
is  that  ft,  =  6  and  ft  =  1/(1  +  fc). 

If  P*  —  P*  is  non-stationary,4  the  empirical  model  analog  of  equation 
(19)  is  (following  Scott) 

For  the  1872  through  1986  period,  we  obtain  OLS  results 

P;-Pt    =       -0.007      +     0.908     (Pt+1-Pt+i) 
(0.007)  (0.039) 

Adj.  R2   =  0.82,    p  =     0.12,      F  =  0.55  (22) 

(0.09) 


5l_^    =       _o.624      +     0.869     (P*+1      Pt+1) 
Dt  (0.404)  (0.046)    V         A         / 

Adj.  R2  =  0.76,    /?  =    0.06,      F  =  1.26  (23) 

(0.09) 

where  the  numbers  in  parentheses  are  standard  errors,  p  is  the  first-order 
autocorrelation  of  the  regression  residual,  and  F  is  the  ^-statistic  with  2 


4One  may  suggest  that  the  absolute  magnitude  of  //<  grows  over  time  as  the  stock  price 
and  the  dividend  grow  over  time. 

8 


and  113  degrees  of  freedom  for  testing  the  joint  hypothesis  of  (30  =  0  and 
ft  =  0.923.  (0.923  =  1/1.0835) 

The  statistical  results  appear  to  be  consistent  with  the  present  value 
model  with  a  constant  discount  rate.  We  reject  none  of  the  following:  (i) 
fa  =  0;  (ii)  ft  =  0.923;  (iii)  the  joint  hypotheses  of  fa  =  0  and  ft  =  0.923. 
The  regression  residual,  which  is  the  estimate  of  the  present  value  of  the 
forecast  error  (f¥j),  is  not  serially  correlated.  This  is  also  consistent  with 
a  rational  forecast  error.  The  latter  result  should  be  interpreted  cautiously. 
As  argued  by  Summers  (1986),  tests  for  autocorrelations  of  single  period 
returns  could  have  extremely  low  power  against  the  inefficient  market  hy- 
pothesis. 

III.  Concluding  Remarks 

This  paper  has  shown  that  the  regression  of  P*  onto  Pt  cannot  detect 
speculative  bubbles  and  has  proposed  an  alternative  test  of  the  present 
value  model.  The  paper  has  tested  whether  the  present  value  relation  holds 
for  the  rational  forecast  error  rjt.  This  approach  has  several  advantages  over 
the  regression  of  P*  onto  Pt.  The  statistical  results  could  not  reject  the 
present  value  model. 


References 

Campbell,  John  Y.,  and  Robert  J.  Shiller,  "Cointegration  and  Tests  of 
Present  Value  Models,"  Journal  of  Political  Economy  vol.  95,  no.  5  (Oc- 
tober 1987),  pp.  1062-88. 

Chow,  Gregory  C,  "Rational  versus  Adaptive  Expectations  in  Present  Value 
Models,"  Review  of  Economics  and  Statistics  vol.  71,  no.  3  (August 
1989),  pp.  376-84. 

Dokko,  Yoon,  "The  Present  Value  Model  and  the  Market  Discount  Rate," 
working  paper,  University  of  Illinois,  1991. 

Flood,  Robert  P.,  and  Peter  M.  Garber,  "Market  Fundamentals  Versus  Price 
Level  Bubbles:  The  First  Test,"  Journal  of  Political  Economy  vol.  88  no. 
3  (August  1980),  pp.  745-70. 

Flood,  Robert  P.,  and  Robert  J.  Hodrick,  "Asset  Price  Volatility,  Bubbles, 
and  Process  Switching,"  Journal  of  Finance  vol.  41,  no.  4  (September 
1986),  pp.  831-42. 

LeRoy,  Stephen,  and  Richard  Porter,  "The  Present  Value  Relation:  Tests 
Based  on  Implied  Variance  Bounds,"  Econometrica  vol.  49,  no.  3  (May 
1981),  pp.  555-74. 

Marsh,  Terry  A.,  and  Robert  C.  Merton,  "Dividend  Variability  and  Variance 
Bounds  Tests  for  the  Rationality  of  Stock  Market  Prices,"  American 
Economic  Review  vol.  76,  no.  3  (June  1986),  pp.  483-98. 

Scott,  Louis  0.,  "The  Present  Value  Model  of  Stock  Prices:  Regression  Tests 
and  Monte  Carlo  Results,"  Review  of  Economics  and  Statistics  vol.  67, 
no.  4  (November  1985),  pp.  599-605. 

Shiller,  Robert  J.,  "Do  Stock  Prices  Move  Too  Much  to  be  Justified  by 
Subsequent  Changes  in  Dividends?"  American  Economic  Review  vol. 
71,  no.  3  (June  1981),  pp.  421-35. 

Shiller,  Robert  J.,  "A  Scott-Type  Regression  Test  of  the  Dividend  Ratio 
Model,"  Review  of  Economics  and  Statistics  vol.  72,  no.  2  (May  1990), 
pp.  356-61. 

Summers,  Lawrence  H.,  "Does  the  Stock  Market  Rationally  Reflect  Fun- 
damental Values?"  Journal  of  Finance  vol.  41,  no.  3  (July  1986),  pp. 
591-601. 


10