Skip to main content

Full text of "Religion And The Rise Of Capitalism Capitalism A Historical Study"

See other formats


AMIEM1DR  BOOK 


261, £5  T23r  71-63381 

Tawney 

Religion  and  the  rise  of  capitalisn 


MAIN 


KANSASCITY    MO    PUBLIC  LIBRARY 


0  OQD1  02^1602  fl 
Religious    1  nought    1  hrough  the   A  get 


DATE      DUE 


MAI 


APR  1  1 


MENTOR  Books  of  Special  Interest 

ETHICS  IN  A  BUSINESS  SOCIETY 

by  Marquis  W.  Childs  and  Douglass  Cater 

A  challenging  analysis  of  the  nature  of  moral  values 
in  the  modern  world.  (#MP392  —  60$) 

THE  THEORY  OF  BUSINESS  ENTERPRISE 

by  Thor  stein  Veblen 

The  Classic  treatise  on  the  place  and  importance  of  the 
businessman  in  maintaining  the  economy 


THE  THEORY  OF  THE  LEISURE  CLASS 

by  Thar  stein  Veblen 

A  provocative  and  ironic  study  of  social  and 
economic  conduct.  Introduction  by  C.  Wright  Mills. 

(#MP401  —  600) 

THE  RICH  AND  THE   POOR:    The   Economics  of 
Rising  Expectations 

by  Robert  Theobald 

A  timely  proposal  for  helping  the  underdeveloped 
countries  may  raise  their  productivity  and  increase 
their  share  of  the  world's  economic  wealth. 

(#MD325—  500) 


RELIGION  AND 
THE  RISE  OF 
CAPITALISM 


A   HISTORICAL   STUDY 

(Holland  Memorial  Lectures,  1922) 


by  R.  H.  TAWNEY 

Reader  in  Economic  History ,  University  of  London; 
Sometime  Fellow  of  Itatliol  College,  Oxford 


A   MENTOR   BOOK 

Published  by  THE  NEW  AMERICAN  LIBRARY 


TO 

DR.  CHARLES  GORE 

WITH 
AFFECTION  AND  GRATITUDE 


COPYRIGHT,  1926,  BY 
HARCOURI,  BRACI  &  WORLD,  INC 

COPYRIGHT,  1954,  BY  R   H   TAWNEY 

All  nglits  te^ened,  unhiding  (lie  n^hl  to  reproduce 
this  hook  or  portions  thereof  in  anv  foim 
For  information  addiess  Han  out  t,  Brace  £  Woild,  Inc  , 
750  Jlurd  A\enue,  New  York  17,  New  Yoik 

Published  as  a  MENTOR  BOOK 

by  arrangement  with  H  anoint,  Brace  &  World,  Inc  , 

who  have  authorized  this  \oft(  over  edition 

FIRST    PRINTING,   NOVIMBFR,    1947 
TWLLFFH  PRINI1NG,  JUNF,    1963 


MENTOR  BOOKS  are  published  in  the  United  States  by 

The  New  American  Library  of  World  Literature,  Inc  , 

501  Madison  Avenue,  New  York  22,  New  York, 

in  Canada  by  rlhe  New  American  Libiary  of  Canada  Limited, 

156  Front  Street  West,  Toronto  1,  Ontario 

PRINTED    IN    THE    UNITED    STA1  I  S    OF    AMLRICA 


Contents 

INTRODUCTION  1 

PREFACE  TO  1937  EDITION  3 

I.     THE  MEDIEVAL  BACKGROUND  11 

The  Social  Organism  20 

The  Sin  of  Avarice  39 

The  Ideal  and  the  Reality  54 

II.     THE  CONTINENTAL  REFORMERS  61 

The  Economic  Revolution  62 

Luther  72 

Calvin  91 

III.  THE  CHURCH  OF  ENGLAND  116 

The  Land  Question  118 

Religious  Theory  and  Social  Policy  128 

The  Growth  of  Individualism  149 

IV.  THE  PURITAN  MOVEMENT  164 

Puritanism  and  Society  165 

A  Godly  Discipline  Versus  the  Religion  of 

Trade  176 

The  Triumph  of  the  Economic  Virtues  189 

The  New  Medicine  for  Poverty  210 

V.     CONCLUSION  227 

NOTES  237 

INDEX            71  {£3381  27 

PITY  rwifi Y?nw  in  i 


ic  Whatever  the  world  thinks,  he  who  hath  not 
much  meditated  upon  God,  the  human  mind  and 
the  summum  bonum,  may  possibly  make  a  thriv- 
ing earthworm,  but  will  most  indubitably  make 
a  sorry  patriot  and  a  sorry  statesman  " 

BISHOP  BERKELEY,  Sins,  350 


Introduction 

TH#  object  of  this  book  is  to  trace  some  strands  in  the  de- 
velopment Of  Religious  thoughlfon  gollal  and  ^  eCojii^jOTTr-^rtr^S" 
ttons  in  the  period  which  saw  the  transition  irorn  medieval 
tP^niudeui  theories  of  social  organization.  "TTcrnes  Tia^Tcarrv 
trie  subject  Jjevtmg^j^ 


tury.  and  it  makes  no  pretense  of  dealing  with  the  history 
either  of  economic  theory  or  of  economic  practice,  except  in 
so  far  as  theory  and  practice  were  related  to  changes  in  re- 
ligious opinion.  In  reality,  however,  the  connection  be- 
tween them  was  intimate  and  vital  The  revolutions,  at 
once  religious,  political  and  social,  which  "herald  tne  transi- 
tion from  the  medieval  to  the  mod  errPworld,  were  hardly 
less  Derisive  foj  the  economic  character  ot  tlie  new  civiliza- 
tion  than  for  its  ecclesiastical  organization  and  religious 
^ortrinfrs  -Trip  pronomir  rafe^ories  of  modern  .society  have 
their  roots  in  the  economic  expansion  and  social  convulsions 
which  accompanied  the  age  of  the  Renaissance  and  the  Re- 
formation"" 

The  history  of  religious  thought  on  questions  of  social 
ethics  is  a  topic  which  has  been  treated  in  England  by  the 
late  Dr  Cunningham,  by  Sir  William  Ashley,  whose  essay 
on  The  Canonist  Doctrine  first  interested  me  in  the  subject, 
by  Mr  G  G  Coulton,  Mr.  H  G.  Wood,  and  Mr.  G. 
O'Brien  But  it  is  no  reflection  on  their  work  to  say  that 
the  most  important  contributions  of  recent  years  have  come 
from  continental  students,  in  particular  Troeltsch,  Choisy, 
Sombart,  Brentano,  Levy  and,  above  all,  Max  Weber,  whose 
celebrated  essay  on  Die  Protestantische  Ethik  und  der  Geist 
des  Kapitalismus  gave  a  new  turn  to  the  discussion.  No 
one  can  work,  on  however  humble  a  scale,  in  the  same  field, 
without  being  conscious  of  the  heavy  obligation  under  which 
these  scholars  have  laid  him  While  I  have  not  always  been 
able  to  accept  their  conclusions,  T  am  glad  to  have  this  op- 
portunity of  expressing  my  indebtedness  to  them.  I  regret 
that  Mr.  Coulton  's  The  Medieval  Village  appeared  too  late 
for  me  to  make  use  of  its  abundant  stores  of  learning  and 
insight. 

It  only  remains  for  me  to  thank  the  friends  whose  as- 
sistance has  enabled  me  to  make  this  book  somewhat  less 


2  INTRODUCTION 

imperfect  than  it  would  otherwise  have  been.  Mr  J  L. 
Hammond,  Dr.  E.  Power,  and  Mr.  A  P  Wadsworth  have 
been  kind  enough  to  read,  and  to  impiove,  the  manuscript. 
Professor  J.  E  Neale,  in  addition  to  reading  the  proofs, 
has  helped  me  most  generously  throughout  with  advice  and 
criticism.  I  am  deeply  indebted  both  to  Miss  Bulkley,  who 
has  undertaken  the  thankless  task  of  correcting  the  proofs 
and  making  an  index,  and  to  the  London  School  of  Eco- 
nomics and  the  Laura  Spelman  Rockefeller  Memorial  Fund 
for  enabling  me  to  make  use  of  her  services.  My  obligation 
to  the  help  given  by  my  wife  is  beyond  acknowledgment 

R.  H.  TAWNEY. 


Prejace   to    IQ3?  Edition 


SINCE  the  appearance  of  this  book  ten  years  ago,  the  litera- 
ture on  its  subject  has  considerably  increased  The  learned 
work  of  Troeltsch,  the  best  introduction  to  the  historical 
study  of  religious  thought  on  social  issues,  can  now  be  read 
in  an  English  translation,  as  can  also  the  articles  of  Weber 
on  The  Protestant  Ethic  and  the  Spirit  of  Capitalism.  The 
omission  from  my  book  of  any  reference  to  post  -Reforma- 
tion Catholic  opinion  was  a  serious  defect,  which  subsequent 
writers  have  done  something  to  repair  The  development 
of  economic  thought  in  mediaeval  Italy,  the  social  forces  at 
work  in  the  Germany  of  Luther,  and  his  attitude  to  them; 
the  economic  doctrines  of  Calvin,  the  teaching  of  the  Jesuits 
on  usury  and  allied  topics,  English  social  policy  during  the 
Interregnum,  the  religious  and  social  outlook  of  the  French 
bouigcoisic  of  the  same  period;  the  attitude  of  Quakers, 
VVesleyans,  and  other  bodies  of  English  Nonconformists  to 
the  chancing  economic  world  which  confronted  them  in  the 
eighteenth  century,  have  all  had  books  devoted  to  them  In 
the  somewhat  lengthy  list  of  articles  on  these  and  kindred 
subjects,  those  by  the  late  Professor  See,  M  Halbwachs, 
and  Mr  Parsons,  and  an  article  by  Mr  Gordon  Walker 
which  has  just  appeared  in  The  Economic  History  Review, 
specially  deserve  attention  x 

It  will  be  seen,  therefore,  that  the  problems  tieated  in  the 
following  pages,  if  they  continue  to  perplex,  have  not  ceased 
to  arouse  interest  What  conclusions,  if  any,  emerge  from 
the  discussion? 

The  most  significant  are  truisms  When  this  book  first 
appeared,  it  was  possible  for  a  friendly  reviewer,  writing  in 
a  serious  journal,  to  deprecate  in  all  gravity  the  employment 
of  the  term  "Capitalism"  in  an  historical  work,  as  a  political 
catch-word,  betraying  a  sinister  intention  on  the  part  of  the 
misguided  author.  An  innocent  solecism  of  the  kind  would 
not,  it  is  probable,  occur  so  readily  today  Obviously,  the 
word  "Capitalism,"  like  "Feudalism"  and  "Meicantilism," 
is  open  to  misuse  Obviously,  the  time  has  now  come  when 
it  is  more  important  to  determine  the  different  species  of 
Capitalism,  and  the  successive  phases  of  its  growth,  than  to 
continue  to  labour  the  existence  of  the  genus.  But,  after 

3 


4  PREFACE    TO    1937    EDITION 

more  than  half  a  century  of  work  on  the  subject  by  scholars 
of  half  a  dozen  different  nationalities  and  of  every  variety 
of  political  opinion,  to  deny  that  the  phenomenon  exists,  or 
to  suggest  that,  if  it  does  exist,  it  is  unique  among  human 
institutions,  in  having,  like  Melchizedek,  existed  from  eter- 
nity; or  to  imply  that,  if  it  has  a  history,  propriety  forbids 
that  history  to  be  disinterred,  is  to  run  willully  in  blinkers 
Verbal  controversies  are  profitless;  if  an  author  discovers  a 
more  suitable  term,  by  all  means  let  him  use  it  He  is  un- 
likely, however,  to  make  much  of  the  history  of  Europe 
during  the  last  three  centuries,  if,  in  addition  to  eschewing 
the  word,  he  ignores  the  fact 

The  more  general  realization  of  the  role  of  Capitalism  in 
history  has  been  accompanied  by  a  second  change,  which,  if 
equally  commonplace,  has  also,  perhaps,  its  significance. 
"Trade  is  one  thing,  religion  is  another":  once  advanced  as 
an  audacious  novelty,  the  doctrine  that  religion  and  eco- 
nomic interests  form  two  separate  and  co-ordinate  king- 
doms, of  which  neither,  without  presumption,  can  encroach 
on  the  other,  was  commonly  accepted  by  the  England  of  the 
nineteenth  century  with  an  unquestioning  assurance  at  which 
its  earliest  exponents  would  have  felt  some  embarrassment 
An  historian  is  concerned  less  to  appraise  the  validity  of  an 
idea  than  to  understand  its  development  The  effects  for 
good  or  evil  of  that  convenient  demarcation,  and  the  forces 
which,  in  our  own  day,  have  caused  the  boundary  to  shift, 
need  not  here  be  discussed.  Whatever  its  merits,  its  victory, 
it  is  now  realized,  was  long  in  being  won  The  economic 
theories  propounded  by  Schoolmen,  the  fulminations  by  the 
left  wing  of  the  Reformers  against  usury,  landgrabbing,  and 
extortionate  prices;  the  appeal  of  hard-headed  Tudor  states- 
men to  traditional  religious  sanctions,  the  attempt  of  Calvin 
and  his  followers  to  establish  an  economic  discipline  more 
rigorous  than  that  which  they  had  overthrown,  are  bad  evi- 
dence for  practice,  but  good  evidence  for  thought  All  rest 
on  the  assumption  that  the  institution  of  property,  the  trans- 
actions of  the  market-place,  the  whole  fabric  of  society  and 
the  whole  range  of  its  activities,  stand  by  no  absolute  title, 
but  must  justify  themselves  at  the  bar  of  religion.  All  in- 
sist that  Christianity  has  no  more  deadly  foe  than  the  ap- 
petitus  divitiarum  infinites,  the  unbridled  indulgence  of  the 
acquisitive  appetite.  Hence  the  claim  that  religion  should 


PREFACE    TO    1937    EDITION  5 

keep  its  hands  off  business  encountered,  when  first  formu- 
lated, a  great  body  of  antithetic  doctrine,  embodied  not  only 
in  literature  and  teaching,  but  in  custom  and  law.  It  was 
only  gradually,  and  after  a  warfare  not  confined  to  paper, 
that  it  affected  the  transition  from  the  status  of  an  odious 
paradox  to  that  of  an  unquestioned  truth 

The  tendency  of  that  transition  is  no  longer  in  dispute. 
Its  causation  and  stages  remain  the  subject  of  debate.  The 
critical  period,  especially  in  England,  was  the  two  centuries 
following  the  Reformation.  It  is  natuFal,  therefore,  IhaT 
most  recent  work  on  the  subject  of  this  book  should  have 
turned  its  high  lights  on  that  distracted  age.  The  most 
striking  attempt  to  formulate  a  theory  of  the  movement  of 
religious  thought  on  social  issues  which  then  took  place  was 
made  at  the  beginning  of  the  present  century  by  a  German 
scholar,  Max  Weber, J  in  two  articles  published  in  1904  and 
1905.  Hence  it  is  not  less  natural  that  much  of  that  work 
should,  consciously  or  unconsciously,  have  had  Weber  as 
its  starting  point 

WThat  exactly  was  the  subject  with  which  he  was  con- 
cerned? That  question  is  obviously  the  first  which  should 
be  asked,  though  not  all  his  critics  ask  it.  He  was  prepar- 
ing to  undertake  the  comparative  study  of  the  social  out- 
look and  influence  of  different  religions,  the  incomplete 
results  of  which  appeared  in  three  volumes  in  1920,  under 
the  name  of  Gcsawmclte  Aujiatzc  zur  Religtonssoztologie. 
The  articles,  Die  protestantischc  Ethik  und  Geist  dcs  Kap- 
italismus,  were  a  first  step  towards  that  larger  work,  and 
subsequently,  corrected  and  amplified,  formed  part  of  its 
first  volume  Weber  thought  that  western  Christianity  as  a 
whole,  and  in  particular  certain  varieties  of  it,  which  ac- 
quired an  independent  life  as  a  result  of  the  Reformation, 
had  been  more  favorable  to  the  progress  of  Capitalism 
than  some  other  great  creeds  His  articles  were  an  attempt 
to  test  that  geneialization 

Their  scope  is  explained  in  an  introduction  written  later 
to  the  Rtligwnssoziologie  His  object  was  to  examine — the 
abstractions  fall  with  a  mournful  thud  on  English  ears — • 
"the  influence  of  certain  religious  ideas  on  the  development 
of  an  economic  spirit  or  the  ethos  of  an  economic  system." 
He  hoped — O  sancta  simplicitas! —  to  avoid  misunderstand- 
ing by  underlining  somewhat  heavily  the  limitations  of  his 


6  PREFACE    TO    1937    EDITION 

theme.  He  formulated  no  "dogma";  on  the  contrary,  he 
emphasized  that  his  articles  were  to  be  regarded  as  merely  a 
Vorarbeit*  a  preparatory  essay.  He  did  not  seek  "a  psy- 
chological determination  of  economic  events",4  on  the  con- 
trary, he  insisted  on  "the  fundamental  importance  of  the 
economic  f actor.  "r>  He  did  not  profess  to  offer  a  complete 
interpretation  even  of  the  religious  attitude  discussed  in  his 
articles;  on  the  contrary,  he  urged  the  necessity  of  investi- 
gating how  that  attitude  itself  tlwas  in  turn  influenced  in  its 
development  and  character  by  the  totality  of  social  condi- 
tions, especially  the  economic  ones  "<(  So  far  from  desiring 
— to  quote  his  own  words — "to  substitute  for  a  one-sided 
'materialistic'  an  equally  one-sided  'spiritual1  interpretation 
of  civilization  and  history,"7  he  expressly  repudiated  any 
intention  of  the  kind. 

In  view  of  these  disclaimers,  it  should  not  be  necessary 
to  point  out  that  Weber  made  no  attempt  in  the  articles  in 
question  to  advance  a  comprehensive  theory  of  the  genesis 
and  growth  of  Capitalism  That  topic  had  been  much  dis- 
cussed in  Germany  since  Marx  opened  the  debate,  and  the 
first  edition  of  the  most  massive  of  recent  books  on  the 
subject,  Sombart's  Dcr  Modcrnc  Kapttalismus,  had  ap- 
peared two  years  before.  The  range  of  Weber's  interests, 
and  the  sweep  of  his  intellectual  vision,  were,  no  doubt, 
unusually  wide;  but  his  earliest  work  had  been  done  on  eco- 
nomic history,  and  he  continued  to  lecture  on  that  subject 
till  his  death  in  1920  If  he  did  not  in  his  articles  refer  to 
the  economic  consequences  of  the  discovery  of  America,  or 
of  the  great  depreciation,  or  of  the  rise  to  financial  pre-emi- 
nence of  the  Catholic  city  of  Antwerp,  it  was  not  that  these 
bashful  events  had  at  last  hit  on  an  historian  whose  notice 
they  could  elude.  Obviously,  they  were  epoch-making;  obvi- 
ously, they  had  a  profound  effect,  not  only  on  economic 
organization,  but  on  economic  thought.  Weber's  immediate 
problem,  however,  was  a  different  one.  Montesquieu  re- 
marked, with  perhaps  excessive  optimism,  that  the  English 
"had  progressed  furthest  of  all  people  in  three  important 
things,  piety,  commerce  and  freedom."  The  debt  of  the  third 
of  these  admirable  attributes  to  the  first  had  often  been 
emphasized.  WTas  it  possible,  Weber  asked,  that  the  sec- 
ond might  also  owe  something  to  it?  He  answered  that 
question  in  the  affirmative.  The  connecting  link  was  to  be 


PREFACE    TO    1937    EDITION  7 

found,  he  thought,  in  the  influence  of  the  religious  move- 
ment whose  greatest  figure  had  been  Calvin. 

Since  Weber's  articles  are  now  available  in  English,  it  is 
needless  to  recapitulate  the  steps  in  his  argument.  My  own 
views  upon  it,  if  1  may  refer  to  them  without  undue  ego- 
tism, were  summarized  in  a  note — too  lengthy  to  be  read — 
to  the  first  edition  of  the  present  work,  and  were  later  re- 
stated more  fully  in  the  introduction  to  the  English  trans- 
lation of  the  articles  which  appeared  in  1930.s  Weber's 
generalizations  had  been  widely  discussed  by  continental 
scholars  for  more  than  twenty  years  before  this  book  ap- 
peared The  criticisms  contained  in  it,  therefore,  had  no 
claim  to  originality — unless,  indeed,  to  be  less  anxious  to 
refute  an  author  than  to  understand  him  is  in  itself  to  be 
original. 

The  first  of  them — that  uthe  development  of  Capitalism 
in  Holland  and  England  in  the  sixteenth  and  seventeenth 
centuries  was  due,  not  to  the  fact  that  they  were  Protestant 
Powers,  but  to  large  economic  movements,  in  particular  the 
Discoveries  and  the  results  which  flowed  from  them" — has 
since  been  developed  at  some  length  by  Mr.  Robertson;  but 
it  was  not,  perhaps,  quite  just.  Weber  would  have  replied, 
no  doubt,  that  such  a  remark,  however  true,  was  as  far  as 
his  articles  were  concerned,  an  ignoratio  elenchi.  To  meet 
him  fairly,  he  would  have  said,  one  should  meet  him  on  his 
own  ground,  which  at  the  moment  was  that,  not  of  general 
economic  history,  but  of  religious  thought  on  social  issues. 
My  second  comment,  already  made  by  Brentano — that  more 
weight  should  have  been  given  to  the  political  thought  of 
the  Renaissance — had  been  anticipated  by  Weber,4  and  I 
regret  that  I  overlooked  his  observations  on  that  point.  His 
gravest  weaknesses  in  his  own  special  field,  where  alone 
criticism  is  relevant,  are  not  those  on  which  most  emphasis 
has  usually  been  laid  The  Calvinist  applications  of  the 
doctrine  of  the  "Calling"  have,  doubtless,  their  significance; 
but  the  degree  of  influence  which  they  exercised,  and  their 
affinity  or  contrast  with  other  versions  of  the  same  idea,  are 
matters  of  personal  judgment,  not  of  precise  proof.  Both 
Weber  and  his  critics  have  made  too  much  of  them,  as  I  did 
myself.  His  account  of  the  social  theory  of  Calvinism, 
however,  if  it  rightly  underlined  some  points  needing  em- 
phasis, left  a  good  deal  unsaid.  The  lacunae  in  his  argu- 


8  PREFACE    TO    1937    EDITION 

ment  cannot  here  be  discussed,  but  two  of  them  deserve  no- 
tice. Though  some  recent  attempts  to  find  parallels  to  that 
theory  in  contemporary  Catholic  writers  have  not  been  very 
happy,  Weber  tended  to  treat  it  as  more  unique  than  it  was.10 
More  important,  he  exaggerated  its  stability  and  consist- 
ency. Taking  a  good  deal  of  his  evidence  from  a  somewhat 
late  phase  in  the  history  of  the  movement,  he  did  not  em- 
phasize sufficiently  the  profound  changes  through  which 
Calvinism  passed  in  the  century  following  the  death  of 
Calvin. 

The  last  point  is  of  some  moment  It  suggests  that  the 
problem  discussed  by  Weber  requires  to  be  restated.  It  is 
natural,  no  doubt,  that  much  of  the  later  work  on  the  sub- 
ject should  have  taken  him  for  its  target,  and  probably  in- 
evitable— such  is  the  nature  of  controversy — that  a  theory 
which  he  advanced  as  a  hypothesis  to  explain  one  range  of 
phenomena,  and  one  alone,  should  have  been  clothed  for  the 
purpose  of  criticism  with  the  uncompromising  finality  of  a 
remorseless  dogma.  His  mine  has  paid  handsome  dividends, 
but,  whatever  its  attractions,  that  vein,  it  may  be  suggested, 
is  now  worked  out  The  important  question,  after  all,  is 
not  what  Weber  wrote  about  the  facts,  still  less  what  the 
epigoni  who  take  in  his  washing  have  suggested  that  he 
wrote,  but  what  the  facts  were  It  is  an  illusion  to  suppose 
that  he  stands  alone  in  pointing  to  a  connection  between  the 
religious  movements  of  the  sixteenth  and  seventeenth  cen- 
turies and  the  outburst  of  economic  energy  which  was  re- 
making society  in  the  Netherlands  and  'England  Other 
students  have  reached,  independently  of  him,  that  not  re- 
condite conclusion11  How  much  truth  does  it  contain? 

To  attempt  a  reply  to  that  question  would  expand  a  pref- 
ace into  a  book  The  materials  for  answering  it  are,  how- 
ever, abundant.  If  contemporary  opinion  on  the  point  is 
not  easily  cited,  the  difficulty  arises,  not  from  lack  of  evi- 
dence to  reveal  it,  but  from  the  embarras  dc  richessc  which 
it  offers  for  quotation  Its  tenor  is  not  doubtful.  The  truth 
is  that  the  ascription  to  different  confessions  of  distinctive 
economic  attitudes  was  not  exceptional  in  the  seventeenth 
century;  among  writers  who  handled  such  topics  it  was 
almost  common  form.  It  occurs  repeatedly  in  works  of 
religious  controversy.  It  occurs  also  in  books,  such  as  those 
of  Temple,  Petty,  and  Defoe,  and  numerous  pamphlets, 


PREFACE    TO    1937    EDITION  9 

by  men  whose  primary  interest  was,  not  religion,  but  eco- 
nomic affairs  So  far,  in  fact,  from  being,  as  has  been  sug- 
gested12 with  disarming  naivete,  the  sinister  concoction  of 
a  dark  modern  conspiracy,  designed  to  confound  Calvinism 
and  Capitalism,  godly  Geneva  and  industrious  Manchester, 
in  a  common  ruin,  the  existence  of  a  connection  between 
economic  Radicalism  and  religious  Radicalism  was  to  those 
who  saw  both  at  first-hand  something  not  far  from  a 
platitude  Until  some  reason  is  produced  for  rejecting  their 
testimony,  it  had  better  be  assumed  that  they  knew  what 
they  were  talking  about. 

How  precisely  that  connection  should  be  conceived  is,  of 
course,  a  different  question  It  had,  obviously,  two  sides. 
Religion  influenced,  to  a  degree  which  to-day  is  difficult  to 
appreciate,  men's  outlook  on  society.  Economic  and  social 
changes  acted  powerfully  on  religion.  Weber,  as  was  natural 
in  view  of  his  special  interests,  emphasized  the  first  point. 
He  did  so  with  a  wealth  of  knowledge  and  an  intellectual 
force  which  deserve  admiration,  and  not  least  the  admira- 
tion of  those  who,  like  myself,  have  ventured  to  dissent 
from  some  of  his  conclusions.  He  touched  the  second 
point  only  en  passant.  There  is  truth  in  the  criticism  of  Mr. 
Gordon  Walker  that  Weber  did  not  inquire  how  far  the 
Reformation  was  a  response  to  social  needs,  or  investigate 
the  causes,  as  well  as  the  consequences,  of  the  religious 
mentality  which  he  analysed  with  so  much  insight 

It  is  that  aspect  of  the  subject  which  most  needs  work 
to-day.  In  the  triple  reconstruction,  political,  ecclesiastical, 
and  economic,  through  which  England  passed  between  the 
Armada  and  the  Revolution,  every  ingredient  in  the  caldron 
worked  a  subtle  change  in  every  other.  There  was  action 
and  reaction  "L/esprit  calviniste,"  and  'Tespnt  des  hommes 
nouveaux  que  la  revolution  economique  du  temps  introduit 
dans  la  vie  des  affaires/7 13  if  in  theory  distinct,  were  in 
practice  intertwined  Puritanism  helned  to  mould  the  social 
order,  but  it  was  also  itself  increasingly  moulded  by  it.  Of 
the  influence  of  the  economic  expansion  of  the  age  on  Eng- 
lish religious  thought  something  is  said  in  the  following 
pages.  I  hope  that  their  inadequacies  may  prompt  some 
more  competent  writer  to  deal  with  that  subject  as  its  im- 
portance deserves. 

R.  H.  TAWNEY 


CHAPTER  I 

The  Medieval  Background 

"La  misencorde  de  Dieu  est  infinie :  elle  sauvera  meme  un  riche.** 
ANATOLE  FRANCE,  Le  Puili  de  Sainte  Claire. 

UQ\JE  pourrions-nous  gagner,"  once  wrote  a  celebrated 
economist,  "a  recueillir  des  opinions  absurdes,  des  doctrines 
decriees,  et  qui  meritent  de  Fetre?  II  serait  a  la  fois  inutile 
et  fastidieux  de  les  exhumer."1  One  who  ^studies  the  de- 
yelopment  of  social  theory  can  hardly  hope  to  avoid  tne 
criticism  whic"h  lg  brought  against  those  who  disturb  the 
dust  in  forgotten  lumber-rooms.  If  he  seeks  an  excuse  be- 
yond his  own  curiosity,  he  may  find  it,  perhaps,  in  the  re- 
flection that  the  past  reveals  to  the  present  what  the  present 
is^capable  of  seeing,  and  tnat  the  lace  wnicn  to  one  ag"e~ls 
ablank _lo  aiiuiJiHr-  \w  pfrpprnant  with  meaning.  WnTmg 
when  economic  science  was  in  the  first  Hush  ot  its  dogmatic 
youth,  it  was  natural  that  Say  should  dismiss  as  an  un- 
profitable dilettantism  an  interest  in  the  speculations  of  ages 
unillumined  by  the  radiance  of  the  new  Gospel.  But  to  de- 
termine the  significance  of  opinion  is,  perhaps,  not  alto- 
gether so  simple  a  matter  as  he  supposed  Since  the  brave 
days  when  Torrens  could  say  of  Political  Economy,  "Twenty 
years  hence  there  will  scarcely  exist  a  doubt  respecting  any 
of  its  fundamental  principles/'2  how  many  confident  certain- 
ties have  been  undermined!  How  many  doctrines  once  dis- 
missed as  the  emptiest  of  superstitions  have  revealed  an  un- 
suspected vitality' 

The  attempt  to  judge  economic  activity  and  social  or- 
ganization by  ethical  criteria  raises  problems  which  are 
eternal,  and  it  is  possible  that  a  study  of  the  thought  of  an 
age  when  that  attempt  was  made,  if  with  little  success,  at 
least  with  conviction  and  persistence,  may  prove,  even  to- 
day, not  wholly  without  instruction.  In  the  present  century, 
the  old  issues  seem,  indeed,  to  have  acquired  a  new  actual- 
ity. The  philosophy  which  would  keep  economic  interests 
and  ethical  idealism  safely  locked  up  in  their  separate  com- 
partments finds  that  each  of  the  prisoners  is  increasingly 
restive  On  the  one  hand,  it  is  evident  that  the  whole  body 
of  regulations,  by  which  modern  societies  set  limits  to  the 

11 


12  THE  MEDIEVAL  BACKGROUND 

free  play  of  economic  self-interest,  implies  the  acceptance, 
whether  deliberate  or  unconscious,  of  moral  standards,  by 
reference  to  which  certain  kinds  of  economic  conduct  are 
pronounced  illegitimate.  On  the  other  hand,  there  are  indi- 
cations that  religious  thought  is  no  longer  content  to  dis- 
miss the  transactions  of  business  and  the  institutions  of 
society  as  matters  irrelevant  to  the  life  of  the  spirit. 

Silently,  but  unmistakably,  the  conception  of  the  scope 
and  content  of  Christian  ethics  which  was  generally,  though 
not  universally,  accepted  in  the  ninPtP0"^  Tntnrv^  is  un- 
dergoing a  revisiont  and  in  that  revision  the  appeal  to  the 
experience  of  mankind,  which  is  history,  has  played  some 
part,  and  will  play  a  larger  one.  There  have  been  periods 
in  which  a  tacit  agreement,  accepted  in  practice  if  not  stated 
in  theory,  excluded  economic  activities  and  social  institu- 
tions from  examination  or  criticism  in  the  light  of  religion 
A  statesman  of  the  early  nineteenth  century,  whose  concep- 
tion of  the  relations  of  Church  and  State  appears  to  have 
been  modeled  on  those  of  Mr.  Collins  and  Lady  Catherine 
de  Bourgh,  is  said  to  have  crushed  a  clerical  reformer  with 
the  protest,  "Things  have  come  to  a  prpf.tv  pa<^  if  rpliprirm 
is  goin£jju-4ftt£r-£prp  ^it^  private  life."  and  a  more  recent 
occupant  of  his  office  has  explained  the  catastrophe  which 
must  follow,  if  the  Church  crosses  the  Rubicon  which  di- 
vides the  outlying  provinces  of  the  spirit  from  the  secular 
capital  of  public  affairs  " 

Whatever  the  merit  of  these  aphorisms,  it  is  evident  to- 
day that  the  line  of  division  between  the  spheres  of  religion 
and  secular  business,  which  they  assume  as  self-evident,  is 
shifting.  By  common  consent  the  treaty  of  partition  has 
lapsed  and  the  boundaries  are  once  more  in  motion  The  age 
of  which  Froude,  no  romantic  admirer  of  ecclesiastical  pre- 
tensions, could  write,  with  perhaps  exaggerated  severity, 
that  the  spokesmen  of  religion  "leave  the  present  world  to 
the  men  of  business  and  the  devil,"  4  shows  some  signs  of 
drawing  to  a  close  Rightly  or  wrongly,  with  wisdom  or 
with  its  opposite,  not  only  in  England  but  on  the  Continent 
and  in  America,  not  only  in  one  denomination  but  among 
Roman  Catholics,  Anglicans,  and  Nonconformists,  jan  at- 
tempt is  being  made  to  restatethepractical 


nf  fhe  Christian  taith,m  a  form  sufficiently 
comprehensive  to  provide  a  standard  by^  which  to  judge  the 


THE  MEDIEVAL  BACKGROUND  13 

collective  actions  and  institutions  of  mankind,  in  the  sphere 
both  of  international  politics  and  of  social  organization.  It 
is  being  made  today.  It  has  been  made  in  the  past.  Whether 
it  will  result  in  any  new  synthesis,  whether  in  the  future  at 
some  point  pushed  farther  into  the  tough  world  of  practical 
affairs  men  will  say, 

Here  nature  first  begins 
Her  farthest  veige,  and  chaos  to  retire 
As  from  her  outmost  works,  a  broken  foe, 

will  not  be  known  by  this  generation.  What  is  certain  is 
that,  as  in  the  analogous  problem  of  the  relations  between 
Church  and  State,  issues  which  were  thought  to  have  been 
buried  by  the  discretion  of  centuries  have  shown  in  our  own 
day  that  they  were  not  dead,  but  sleeping  To  examine  the 
forms  which  they  have  assumed  arid  the  phases  through 
which  they  have  passed,  even  in  the  narrow  field  of  a  single 
country  and  a  limited  period,  is  not  mere  antiquarianism. 
It  is  to  summon  the  living,  not  to  invoke  a  corpse,  dnd  to 
see  from  a  new  angle  the  problems  of  our  own  age,  by  wid- 
ening the  experience  brought  to  their  consideration. 

In  such  an  examination  the  sixteenth  and  seventeenth 
centuries  are  obviously  a  critical  period.  Dr.  Figgis5  has 
described  the^  secularization  of  political  theory  as  the  most 
momentous  of  the  infplW<iifl1  changes  wtii£]i  ushereJlrTthe 
modem  workL  Tt  was  not  the  less  revolutionary  jk£causeit 
jyas_only  gradually  that  its  full  consequences  became  lippaP" 
~enT7  si)  IhRt  Seeds  whicn  were  sown  before  the  Reformation 
yielded  their  fruit  in  England  only  after  the  Civil  War. 
The  political  aspects  of  the  transformation  are  familiar. 
The  ineological  mould  which  shaped  political  Jhe^yTrom 
the  Middle  Ages  to  tiie  seven  teeiilli  cWlLUfy  ijLbroken;  poli- 
tics becomes  a  science,  ultimately  a  group  of  sciences,  and 
theology  at  best  one  science  among  others.  Reason  takes 
the  place  of  revelation,  and  the  criterion  of  political  insti- 
tutions is  expediency,  not  religious  authority.  .  Religion. 
ceasing  to  be  the  master-interest  of  mankind,  dwindles  into 
a  department  of  life  with  boundaries  which  it  fc 
~  ""  """" 


The  ground  which  it  vacates  is  occupied  by  a  new  insti- 
tution, armed  with  a  novel  doctrine.  If  the  Church  of  the 


14  THE  MEDIEVAL  BACKGROUND 

Middle  Ages  was  a  kind  of  State,  the  State  of  the  Tudors 
had  some  of  the  characteristics  of  a  Church;  and  it  was 
precisely  the  impossibility,  for  all  but  a  handful  of  sectaries, 
of  conceiving  a  society  which  treated  religion  as  a  thing  pri- 
vately vital  but  publicly  indifferent,  which  in  England  made 
irreconcilable  the  quarrel  between  Puritanism  and  the  mon- 
archy. When  the  mass  had  been  heated  in  the  furnace  of 
the  Civil  War,  its  component  parts  were  ready  to  be  disen- 
gaged from  each  other.  By  the  end  of  the  seventeenth  cen- 
tury thesecular  State,  separate  from  the  Churches,  wETcK 
are  subordinate  to  it,  hji£j^ieige(TTrbm  the  theory  which 
had  regarded  both  as^duaTaspeas  of  U  single  soCtely.  'The 
former  pays  a  shadowy  deference  to  religion;  the  latter  do 
not  meddle  with  the  external  fabric  of  the  political  and  so- 
cial system,  which  is  the  concern  of  the  former  The  age 
of  religious  struggles  virtually  ends  with  the  Treaty  of 
Westphalia  in  1648  The  age  of  the  wars  of  economic 
nationalism  virtually  begins  with  the  war  between  Eng- 
land and  Holland  under  the  Comonwealth  and  Charles  II 
The  State,  first  in  England,  then  in  France  and  America, 
finds  its  sanction,  not  in  religion,  but  in  nature,  in  a  pre- 
sumed contract  to  establish  it,  in  the  necessity  for  mutual 
protection  and  the  convenience  of  mutual  assistance.  It  ap- 
peals to  no  supernatural  commission,  but  exists  to  protect 
individuals  in  the  enjoyment  of  those  absolute  rights  which 
were  vested  in  them  by  the  immutable  laws  of  nature  "The 
great  and  chief  end  of  men  uniting  into  commonwealths  and 
putting  themselves  under  government  is  the  preservation  of 
their  property."  6 

While  the  political  significance  of  this  development  has 
often  been  described,  the  analogous  changes  in  social  and 
economic  thought  have  received  less  attention.  They  were, 
however,  momentous,  and  deserve  consideration  The  emer- 
gence of  an  objective  and  passionless  economic  science 
took  place  more  slowly  than  the  corresponding  movement 
in  the  theory  of  the  State,  because  the  issues  were  less  ab- 
sorbing, and,  while  one  marched  in  the  high  lights  of  the 
open  stage,  the  other  lurked  on  the  back  stairs  and  in  the 
wings.  It  was  not  till  a  century  after  Machiavelli  had 
emancipated  the  State  from  religion,  that  the  doctrine  of 
the  self-contained  department  with  laws  of  its  own  begins 
generally  to  be  applied  to  the  world  of  business  relations. 


THE  MEDIEVAL  BACKGROUND  IS 

and  even  in  the  England  of  the  early  seventeenth  century, 
to  discuss  questions  of  economic  organization  purely  in 
terms  of  pecuniary  profit  and  loss  still  wears  an  air  of  not 
quite  reputable  cynicism.  When  the  sixteenth  century  opens, 
not  only  political  but  social  theory  is  saturated  with  doc- 
trines drawn  from  the  sphere  of  ethics  and  religion,  and 
economic  phenomena  are  expressed  in  terms  of  personal 
conduct,  as  naturally  and  inevitably  as  the  nineteenth  cen- 
tury expressed  them  in  terms  of  mechanism. 

Not  the  least  fundamental  of  divisions  among  theories  of 
society  is  between  those  which  regard  the  world  of  human 
affairs  as  self-contained,  and  those  which  appeal  to  a  super- 
natural criterion  Modern  social  theory,  like  modern  politi- 
cal theory,  develops  only  when  society  is  given  a  naturalistic 
instead  of  a  religious  explanation,  and  a  capital  fact  which 
presides  at  the  birth  of  both  is  a  change  in  the  conception 
held  of  the  nature  and  functions  of  a  Church  The  crucial 
period  is  the  sixteenth  and  seventeenth  centuries.  The  most 
important  arena  (apart  from  Holland)  is  England,  because 
it  is  in  England,  with  its  new  geographical  position  as  the 
entrepot  between  Europe  and  America,  its  achievement  of 
internal  economic  unity  two  centuries  before  France  and 
two  and  a  half  centuries  before  Germany,  its  constitutional 
revolution,  and  its  powerful  bourgeoisie  of  bankers,  ship- 
owners, and  merchants,  that  the  transformation  of  the  struc- 
ture of  society  is  earliest,  swiftest,  and  most  complete.  Its 
essence  is  the  secularization  of  social  and  economic  phi- 
losophy The  synthesis  is  resolved  into  its  elements — poli- 
tics, business,  and  spiritual  exercises,  each  assumes  a  sep- 
arate and  independent  vitality  and  obeys  the  laws  of  its  own 
being  The  social  functions  matured  within  the  Church, 
and  long  identified  with  it,  are  transferred  to  the  State, 
which  in  turn  is  idolized  as  the  dispenser  of  prosperity  and 
the  guardian  of  civilization  The  theory  of  a  hierarchy  of 
valuer,  embracing  all  human  interests  and  activities  in  a 
system  of  which  the  apex  is  religion,  is  replaced  by  the 
conception  of  separate  and  parallel  compartments,  between 
which  a  due  balance  should  be  maintained,  but  which  have 
no  vital  connection  with  each  other. 

The  intellectual  movement  is,  of  course,  very  gradual, 
and  is  compatible  with  both  throw-backs  and  precocities 
which  seem  to  refute  its  general  character.  It  is  easy  to  de« 


16  THE  MEDIEVAL  BACKGROUND 

tect  premonitions  of  the  coming  philosophy  in  the  later 
Middle  Ages,  and  reversions  to  an  earlier  manner  at  the  very 
end  of  the  seventeenth  century.  Oresme  in  the  fourteenth 
century  can  anticipate  the  monetary  theory  associatd  with 
the  name  of  Gresham;  in  the  fifteenth  century  Laurentius 
de  Rudolfis  can  distinguish  between  trade  bills  and  finance 
bills,  and  St.  Antonino  describe  the  significance  of  capital; 
while  Baxter  in  1673  can  write  a  Christian  Directory  in 
the  style  of  a  medieval  Summa,  and  Bunyan  in  1680  can 
dissect  the  economic  iniquities  of  Mr.  Badman,  who  ground 
the  poor  with  high  prices  and  usury,  in  the  manner  of  a 
medieval  friar  7  But  the  distance  traversed  in  the  two  cen- 
turies between  1500  and  1700  is,  nevertheless,  immense  At 
the  earlier  date,  though  economic  rationalism  has  proceeded 
far  in  Italy,  the  typical  economic  systems  are  those  of  the 
Schoolmen,  the  typical  popular  teaching  is  that  of  the  ser- 
mon, or  of  manuals  such  as  Dives  et  Pauper;  the  typical 
appeal  in  difficult  cases  of  conscience  is  to  the  Bible,  the 
Fathers,  the  canon  law  and  its  interpreters;  the  typical  con- 
troversy is  carried  on  in  terms  of  morality  and  religion  as 
regularly  and  inevitably  as  two  centuries  later  it  is  con- 
ducted in  terms  of  economic  expediency. 

It  is  not  necessary  to  point  out  that  the  age  of  Henry 
VIII  and  Thomas  Cromwell  had  nothing  to  learn  from  the 
twentieth  century  as  to  the  niceties  of  political  intrigue  or 
commercial  sharp  practice.  But  a  cynical  unscrupulousness 
in  high  places  is  not  incompatible  with  a  general  belief  in 
the  validity  of  moral  standards  which  are  contradicted  by  it. 
No  one  can  read  the  discussions  which  took  place  between 
1500  and  1550  on  three  burning  issues — the  rise  in  prices, 
capital  and  interest,  and  the  land  question  in  England — 
without  being  struck  by  the  constant  appeal  from  the  new 
and  clamorous  economic  interests  of  the  day  to  the  tradi- 
tional Christian  morality,  which  in  social  organization,  as 
in  the  relations  of  individuals,  is  still  conceived  to  be  the 
final  authority.  It  is  because  it  is  regarded  as  the  final  au- 
thority that  the  officers  of  the  Church  claim  to  be  heard  on 
questions  of  social  policy;  and  that,  however  Catholics,  An- 
glicans, Lutherans,  and  Calvinists  may  differ  on  doctrine  or 
ecclesiastical  government,  Luther  and  Calvin,  Latimer  and 
Laud,  John  Knox  and  the  Pilgrim  Fathers  are  agreed  that 
social  morality  is  the  province  of  the  Church,  and  are  pre- 


THE  MEDIEVAL  BACKGROUND  17 

pared  both  to  teach  it,  and  to  enforce  it,  when  necessary,  by 
suitable  discipline. 

By  the  middle  of  the  seventeenth  century  all  that  is  al- 
tered. After  the  Restoration,  we  are  in  a  new  world  of 
economic,  as  well  as  of  political,  thought.  The  claim  of 
religion,  at  best  a  shadowy  claim,  to  maintain  rules  of  good 
conscience  in  economic  affairs  finally  vanished  with  the  de- 
struction of  Laud's  experiment  in  a  confessional  State,  and 
with  the  failure  of  the  work  of  the  Westminster  Assembly. 
After  the  Civil  War,  the  attempt  to  maintain  the  theory 
that  there  was  a  Christian  standard  of  economic  conduct 
was  impossible,  not  only  because  of  lay  opposition,  but  be- 
cause the  division  of  the  Churches  made  it  evident  that  no 
common  standard  existed  which  could  be  enforced  by  ec- 
clesiastical machinery.  The  doctrine  of  the  Restoration 
economists,8  that,  as  proved  by  the  experience  of  Holland, 
trade  and  tolerance  flourished  together,  had  its  practical  sig- 
nificance in  the  fact  that  neither  could  prosper  without  large 
concessions  to  individualism 

The  ground  which  is  vacated  by  the  Christian  moralist 
is  quickly  occupied  by  theorists  of  another  order.  The 
future  for  the  next  two  hundred  years  is  not  with  the  at- 
tempt to  reaffirm,  with  due  allowance  for  altered  circum- 
stances, the  conception  that  a  moral  rule  is  binding  on  Chris- 
tians in  their  economic  transactions,  but  with  the  new  sci- 
ence of  Political  Arithmetic,  which  asserts,  at  first  with  hesi- 
tation and  then  with  confidence,  that  no  moral  rule  beyond 
the  letter  of  the  law  exists.  Influenced  in  its  method  by  the 
contemporary  progress  of  mathematics  and  physics,  it  han- 
dles economic  phenomena,  not  as  a  casuist,  concerned  to  dis- 
tinguish right  from  wrong,  but  as  a  scientist,  applying  a  new 
calculus  to  impersonal  economic  forces  Its  method,  temper, 
and  assumptions  are  accepted  by  all  educated  men,  including 
the  clergy,  even  though  its  particular  conclusions  continue 
for  long  to  be  disputed.  Its  greatest  English  exponent,  be- 
fore the  days  of  Adam  Smith,  is  the  Reverend  Dr.  Tucker, 
Dean  of  Gloucester. 

Some  of  the  particular  stages  in  this  transition  will  be 
discussed  later.  But  that  there  was  a  transition,  and  that 
the  intellectual  and  moral  conversion  which  it  produced  was 
not  less  momentous  than  the  effect  of  some  more  familiar 
intellectual  revolutions,  is  undeniable.  Nor  is  it  to  be  re- 


18  THE  MEDIEVAL  BACKGROUND 

futed  by  insisting  that  economic  motives  and  economic  needs 
are  as  old  as  history,  or  that  the  appeal  to  religion  is  often 
a  decorous  drapery  for  a  triumphant  materialism.  A  me- 
dieval cynic,  in  expounding  the  canon  law  as  to  usury,  re- 
marked that  "he  who  takes  it  goes  to  hell,  and  he  who  does 
not  goes  to  the  workhouse."  9  Mr.  Coulton  does  well  to  re- 
mind us  that,  even  in  the  Age  of  Faith,  resounding  princi- 
ples were  compatible  with  very  sordid  practice.  In  a  dis- 
cussion which  has  as  its  subject  social  thought,  not  the  his- 
tory of  business  organization,  it  is  not  necessary  to  elab- 
orate that  truism.  Only  the  credulous  or  the  disillusioned 
will  contrast  successive  periods  as  light  with  darkness  or 
darkness  with  light,  or  yield  to  the  temper  which  finds  ro- 
mantic virtues  in  every  age  except  its  own.  To  appraise  the 
merits  of  different  theories  of  social  organization  must  be 
left  to  those  who  feel  confident  that  they  possess  an  ade- 
quate criterion.  All  that  can  be  attempted  in  these  pages 
is  to  endeavor  to  understand  a  few  among  them. 

For,  after  all,  because  doctrine  and  conduct  diverge,  it 
does  not  follow  that  to  examine  the  former  is  to  hunt  ab- 
stractions. That  men  should  have  thought  as  they  did  is 
sometimes  as  significant  as  that  they  should  have  acted  as 
they  did,  and  not  least  significant  when  thought  and  prac- 
tice are  at  variance.  It  may  be  true  that  "theory  is  a  criti- 
cism of  life  only  in  the  same  sense  as  a  good  man  is  a  criti- 
cism of  a  bad  one  "  But  the  emphasis  of  the  theorist  on 
certain  aspects  and  values  is  not  arbitrary,  but  is  itself  an 
interpretation,  and,  if  his  answers  are  to  be  discounted,  his 
questions  are  none  the  less  evidence  as  to  the  assumptions 
of  the  period  in  which  they  were  asked.  It  would  be  para- 
doxical to  dismiss  Machiavelli  and  Locke  and  Smith  and 
Bentham  as  irrelevant  to  the  political  practice  of  their  age, 
merely  on  the  ground  that  mankind  has  still  to  wait  for  the 
ideal  Prince  or  Whig  or  Individualist  or  Utilitarian.  It  is 
not  less  paradoxical  to  dismiss  those  who  formulated  eco- 
nomic and  social  theories  in  the  Middle  Ages  or  in  the  six- 
teenth century  merely  because,  behind  canon  law  and  sum- 
mae  and  sermons,  behind  the  good  ordinances  of  borough 
and  gild,  behind  statutes  and  proclamations  and  prerogative 
courts,  there  lurked  the  immutable  appetites  of  the  eco- 
nomic man. 

There  is  an  evolution  of  ideas,  as  well  as  of  organisms, 


THE  MEDIEVAL  BACKGROUND  19 

and  the  quality  of  civilization  depends,  as  Professor  Wallas 
has  so  convincingly  shown,  on  the  transmission,  less  of  phys- 
ical qualities,  than  of  a  complex  structure  of  habits,  knowl- 
edge, and  beliefs,  the  destruction  of  which  would  be  fol- 
lowed within  a  year  by  the  death  of  half  the  human  race. 
Granted  that  the  groundwork  of  inherited  dispositions  with 
which  the  individual  is  born  has  altered  little  in  recorded 
history,  the  interests  and  values  which  compose  his  world 
have  undergone  a  succession  of  revolutions.  The  conven- 
tional statement  that  human  nature  does  not  change  is  plau- 
sible only  so  long  as  attention  is  focused  on  those  aspects  of 
it  which  are  least  distinctively  human.  The  wolf  is  today 
what  he  was  when  he  was  hunted  by  Nirnrod.  But,  while 
men  are  born  with  many  of  the  characteristics  of  wolves, 
man  is  a  wulf  domesticated,  who  both  transmits  the  arts 
by  which  he  has  been  partially  tamed  and  improves  upon 
them  He  stens  into  a  social  inheritance,  to  which  each 
generation  adds  its  own  contribution  of  good  and  evil,  be- 
fore it  bequeaths  it  to  its  successors. 

There  is  a  moral  and  religious,  as  well  as  a  material,  en- 
vironment, which  sets  its  stamp  on  the  individual,  even 
when  he  is  least  conscious  of  it  And  the  effect  of  changes 
in  this  environment  is  not  less  profound.  The  economic 
categories  of  modern  society,  such  as  pioperty,  freedom  of 
contract  and  competition,  are  as  much  a  part  of  its  intel- 
lectual furniture  as  its  political  conceptions,  and,  together 
with  religion,  have  probably  been  the  most  potent  force  in 
giving  it  its  character  Between  the  conception  of  society 
as  a  community  of  unequal  classes  with  varying  functions, 
organized  for  a  common  end,  and  that  which  regards  it  as  a 
mechanism  adjuring  itself  through  the  play  of  economic 
motives  to  the  supply  of  economic  needs;  between  the  idea 
that  a  man  miibt  not  take  advantage  of  his  neighbor's  neces- 
sity, and  the  doctrine  that  "man's  self-love  is  God's  provi- 
dence"; between  the  attitude  which  appeals  to  a  religious 
standard  to  repress  economic  appetites,  and  that  which  re- 
gards expediency  as  the  final  criterion — there  is  a  chasm 
which  no  theory  of  the  permanence  and  ubiquity  of  eco- 
nomic interests  can  bridge,  and  which  deserves  at  least  to 
be  exploied  To  examine  how  the  latter  grew  out  of  the 
former;  to  trace  the  change,  from  a  view  of  economic  ac- 
tivity which  regarded  it  as  one  among  other  kinds  of  moral 


20  THE  MEDIEVAL  BACKGROUND 

conduct,  to  the  view  of  it  as  dependent  upon  impersonal 
and  almost  automatic  forces;  to  observe  the  struggle  of  in- 
dividualism, in  the  face  of  restrictions  imposed  in  the  name 
of  religion  by  the  Church  and  of  public  policy  by  the  State, 
first  denounced,  then  palliated,  then  triumphantly  justified 
in  the  name  of  economic  liberty ;  to  watch  how  ecclesiastical 
authority  strives  to  maintain  its  hold  upon  the  spheres  it 
had  claimed  and  finally  abdicates  them — to  do  this  is  not  to 
indulge  a  vain  curiosity,  but  to  stand  at  the  sources  of  rivu- 
lets which  are  now  a  flood. 

Has  religious  opinion  in  the  past  regarded  questions  of 
social  organization  and  economic  conduct  as  irrelevant  to 
the  life  of  the  spirit,  or  has  it  endeavored  not  only  to  chris- 
tianize the  individual  but  to  make  a  Christian  civilization? 
Can  religion  admit  the  existence  of  a  sharp  antithesis  be- 
tween personal  morality  and  the  practices  which  are  per- 
missible in  business?  Does  the  idea  of  a  Church  involve 
the.  acceptance  of  any  particular  standard  of  social  ethics, 
and,  if  so,  ought  a  Church  to  endeavor  to  enforce  it  as 
among  the  obligations  incumbent  on  its  members?  Such  are 
a  few  of  the  questions  which  men  are  asking  today,  and  on 
which  a  more  competent  examination  of  history  than  I  can 
hope  to  offer  might  throw  at  any  rate  an  oblique  and  waver- 
ing light. 

I     THE  SOCIAL  ORGANISM 

We  are  asking  these  questions  today  Men  were  asking 
the  same  question,  thought  in  different  language,  through- 
out the  sixteenth  century.  It  is  a  commonplace  that  modern 
economic  history  begins  with  a  series  of  revolutionary 
changes  in  the  direction  and  organization  of  commerce,  in 
finance,  in  prices,  and  in  agriculture.  To  the  new  economic 
situation  men  brought  a  body  of  doctrine,  law  and  tradi- 
tion, hammered  out  during  the  preceding  three  centuries. 
Since  the  new  forces  were  bewildering,  and  often  shocking, 
to  conservative  consciences,  moralists  and  religious  teachers 
met  them  at  first  by  a  re-affirmation  of  the  traditional  doc- 
trines, by  which,  it  seemed,  their  excesses  might  be  restrained 
and  their  abuses  corrected.  As  the  changed  environment 
became,  not  a  novelty,  but  an  established  fact,  these  doc- 
trines had  to  be  modified.  As  the  effects  of  the  Reformation 


THE    SOCIAL    ORGANISM  21 

developed,  different  churches  produced  characteristic  dif- 
ferences of  social  opinion. 

But  these  were  later  developments,  which  only  gradually 
became  apparent.  The  new  economic  world  was  not  ac- 
cepted without  a  struggle.  Apart  from  a  few  extremists, 
the  first  generation  of  reformers  were  rarely  innovators  in 
matters  of  social  theory,  and  quoted  Fathers  and  church 
councils,  decretals  and  canon  lawyers,  in  complete  uncon- 
sciousness that  innovations  in  doctrine  and  church  govern- 
ment involved  any  breach  with  what  they  had  learned  to 
regard  as  the  moral  tradition  of  Christendom.  Hence  the 
sixteenth  century  sees  a  collision,  not  only  between  different 
schools  of  religious  thought,  but  between  the  changed  eco- 
nomic environment  and  the  accepted  theory  of  society.  To 
understand  it,  one  must  place  oneself  at  the  point  from 
which  it  started.  One  must  examine,  however  summarily, 
the  historical  background. 

That  background  consisted  of  the  body  of  social  theory 
stated  and  implicit,  which  was  the  legacy  of  the  Middle 
Ages.  The  formal  teaching  was  derived  from  the  Bible, 
the  works  of  the  Fathers  and  Schoolmen,  the  canon  law  and 
its  commentators,  and  had  been  popularized  in  sermons  and 
religious  manuals.  The  informal  assumptions  were  those 
implicit  in  law,  custom,  and  social  institutions.  Both  were 
complex,  and  to  speak  of  them  as  a  unity  is  to  sacrifice 
truth  to  convenience.  It  may  be  that  the  political  historian 
is  justified  when  he  covers  with  a  single  phrase  the  five 
centuries  or  more  to  which  tradition  has  assigned  the  title 
of  the  Middle  Ages.  For  the  student  of  economic  condi- 
tions that  suggestion  of  homogeneity  is  the  first  illusion 
to  be  discarded. 

The  medieval  economic  world  was  marked,  it  is  true, 
by  certain  common  characteristics.  They  sprang  from  the 
fact  that  on  the  west  it  was  a  closed  system,  that  on  the 
north  it  had  so  much  elbow-room  as  was  given  by  the  Baltic 
and  the  rivers  emptying  themselves  into  it,  and  that  on  the 
east,  where  it  was  open,  the  apertures  were  concentrated 
along  a  comparatively  short  coast-line  from  Alexandria  to 
the  Black  Sea,  so  that  they  were  easily  commanded  by  any 
naval  power  dominating  the  eastern  Mediterranean,  and  eas- 
ily cut  by  any  military  power  which  could  squat  across  the 
trade  routes  before  they  reached  the  sea.  While,  however, 


22  THE  MEDIEVAL  BACKGROUND 

these  broad  facts  determined  that  the  two  main  currents  of 
trade  should  run  from  east  to  west  and  north  to  south,  and 
that  the  most  progressive  economic  life  of  the  age  should 
cluster  in  the  regions  from  which  these  currents  started 
and  where  they  met,  within  this  general  economic  frame- 
work there  was  the  greatest  variety  of  condition  and  devel- 
opment The  contours  of  economic  civilization  ran  on  dif- 
ferent lines  from  those  of  subsequent  centuries,  but  the 
contrast  between  mountain  and  valley  was  not  less  clearly 
marked.  If  the  sites  on  which  a  complex  economic  struc- 
ture rose  were  far  removed  from  those  of  later  genera- 
tions, it  flourished  none  the  less  where  conditions  favored 
its  growth  In  spite  of  the  ubiquity  of  manor  and  gild, 
there  was  as  much  difference  between  the  life  of  a  center 
of  capitalist  industry,  like  fifteenth-century  Flanders,  or  a 
center  of  capitalist  finance,  like  fifteenth-century  Florence, 
and  a  pastoral  society  exporting  raw  materials  and  a  little 
food,  like  medieval  England,  as  there  is  between  modern 
Lancashire  or  London  and  modern  Denmark  To  draw 
from  English  conditions  a  picture  of  a  whole  world  stagnat- 
ing in  economic  squalor,  or  basking  in  economic  innocence, 
is  as  absurd  as  to  reconstruct  the  economic  life  of  Europe  in 
the  twentieth  century  from  a  study  of  the  Shetland  Islands 
or  the  Ukraine  The  elements  in  the  social  theory  of  the 
Middle  Ages  were  equally  various,  and  equally  changing. 
Even  if  the  student  confines  himself  to  the  body  of  doctrine 
which  is  definitely  associated  with  leligion,  and  takes  as 
typical  of  it  the  Summac  of  the  Schoolmen,  he  finds  it  in 
constant  process  of  development  The  economic  teaching  of 
St.  Antonmo  in  the  fifteenth  century,  for  example,  was  far 
more  complex  and  realistic  than  that  of  St  Thomas  in  the 
thirteenth,  and  down  to  the  very  end  of  the  Middle  Ages 
the  best-established  and  most  characteristic  parts  of  the  sys- 
tem— for  example,  the  theory  of  prices  and  of  usury — so 
far  from  being  stationary,  were  steadily  modified  and  elabo- 
rated. 

There  are,  perhaps,  four  main  attitudes  which  religious 
opinion  may  adopt  toward  the  world  of  social  institutions 
and  economic  relations.  It  may  stand  on  one  side  in  ascetic 
aloofness  and  regard  them  as  in  their  very  nature  the  sphere 
of  unrighteousness,  from  which  men  may  escape — from 
which,  if  they  consider  their  souls,  they  will  escape — but 


THE   SOCIAL   ORGANISM  23 

which  they  can  conquer  only  by  flight.  It  may  take  them 
for  granted  and  ignore  them,  as  matters  of  indifference  be- 
longing to  a  world  with  which  religion  has  no  concern;  in 
all  ages  the  prudence  of  looking  problems  boldly  in  the  face 
and  passing  on  has  seemed  too  self-evident  to  require  justi- 
fication. It  may  throw  itself  into  an  agitation  for  some  par- 
ticular reform,  for  the  removal  of  some  crying  scandal,  for 
the  promotion  of  some  final  revolution,  which  will  inaug- 
urate the  reign  of  righteousness  on  earth.  It  may  at  once 
accept  and  criticize,  tolerate  and  amend,  welcome  the  gross 
world  of  human  appetites,  as  the  squalid  scaffolding  from 
amid  which  the  life  of  the  spirit  must  rise,  and  insist  that 
this  also  is  the  material  of  the  Kingdom  of  God.  To  such 
a  temper,  all  activities  divorced  from  religion  are  brutal  or 
dead,  but  none  are  too  mean  to  be  beneath  or  too  great  to 
be  above  it,  since  all,  in  their  different  degrees,  are  touched 
with  the  spirit  which  permeates  the  whole.  It  finds  its  most 
sublime  expression  in  the  words  of  Piccarda:  "Paradise  is 
everywhere,  though  the  grace  of  the  highest  good  is  not 
shed  every  where  in  the  same  degree." 

Each  of  these  attitudes  meets  us  today.  Each  meets  us 
in  the  thought  of  the  Middle  Ages,  as  differences  of  period 
and  place  and  economic  environment  and  personal  tempera- 
ment evoke  it.  In  the  early  Middle  Ages  the  ascetic  temper 
predominates  Lanfranc,  for  example,  who  sees  nothing  in 
economic  life  but  the  struggle  of  wolves  over  carrion,  thinks 
that  men  of  business  can  hardly  be  saved,  for  they  live  by 
cheating  and  profiteering.10  It  is  monasticism,  with  its  repu- 
diation of  the  prizes  and  temptations  of  the  secular  world, 
which  is  par  excellence  the  life  of  religion.  As  one  phase 
of  it  succumbed  to  ease  and  affluence,  another  rose  to  re- 
store the  primitive  austerity,  and  the  return  to  evangelical 
poverty,  preached  by  St.  Francis  but  abandoned  by  many 
of  his  followers,  was  the  note  of  the  majority  of  move- 
ments for  reform.  As  for  indifferentism — what  else,  for 
all  its  communistic  phrases,  is  Wyclif's  teaching,  that  the 
"just  man  is  already  lord  of  all"  and  that  "in  this  world 
God  must  serve  the  devil,"  but  an  anticipation  of  the  doc- 
trine of  celestial  happiness  as  the  compensation  for  earthly 
misery,  to  which  Hobbes  gave  a  cynical  immortality  when 
he  wrote  that  the  persecuted,  instead  of  rebelling,  "must 
expect  their  reward  in  Heaven,"  and  which  Mr.  and  Mrs* 


24  THE  MEDIEVAL  BACKGROUND 

Hammond  have  revealed  as  an  opiate  dulling  both  the  pain 
and  the  agitation  of  the  Industrial  Revolution?  If  obscure 
sects  like  the  Poor  Men  of  Lyons  are  too  unorthodox  to  be 
cited,  the  Friars  are  not,  and  it  was  not  only  Langland  and 
that  gentlemanly  journalist,  Froissart,  who  accused  them — 
the  phrase  has  a  long  history — of  stirring  up  class  hatred 

To  select  from  so  immense  a  sea  of  ideas  about  society 
and  religion  only  the  specimens  that  fit  the  meshes  of  one's 
own  small  net,  and  to  label  them  "medieval  thought,"  is 
to  beg  all  questions.  Ideas  have  a  pedigree  which,  if  real- 
ized, would  often  embarrass  their  exponents  The  day  has 
long  since  passed  when  it  could  be  suggested  that  only  one- 
half  of  modern  Christianity  has  its  root  in  medieval  re- 
ligion. There  is  a  medieval  Puritanism  and  rationalism 
as  well  as  a  medieval  Catholicism  In  the  field  of 
ecclesiastical  theory,  as  Mr.  Manning  has  pointed  out  in 
his  excellent  book,11  Gregory  VII  and  Boniface  VIII  and 
their  true  successors  in  Calvin  and  Knox  What  is  true  of 
religion  and  political  thought  is  equally  true  of  economic 
and  social  doctrines.  The  social  theories  of  Luther  and 
Latimer,  of  Bucer  and  Bullinger,  of  sixteenth-century  Ana- 
baptists and  seventeenth-century  Levellers,  of  Puritans  like 
Baxter,  Anglicans  like  Laud,  Baptists  like  Bunyan,  Quakers 
like  Sellers,  are  all  the  children  of  medieval  parents  Like 
the  Church  today  in  regions  which  have  not  yet  emerged 
from  savagery,  the  Church  of  the  earlier  Middle  Ages  had 
been  engaged  in  an  immense  missionary  effort,  in  which, 
as  it  struggled  with  the  surrounding  barbarism,  the  work 
of  conversion  and  of  social  construction  had  been  almost 
indistinguishable.  By  the  very  nature  of  its  task,  as  much 
as  by  the  intention  of  its  rulers,  it  had  become  the  greatest 
of  political  institutions  For  good  or  evil  it  aspired  to  be, 
not  a  sect,  but  a  civilization,  and,  when  its  unity  was  shat- 
tered at  the  Reformation,  the  different  Churches  which 
emerged  from  it  endeavored,  according  to  their  different 
opportunities,  to  perpetuate  the  same  tradition  Asceticism 
or  renunciation,  quietism  or  indifferentism,  the  zeal  which 
does  well  to  be  angry,  the  temper  which  seeks  a  synthesis 
of  the  external  order  and  the  religion  of  the  spirit — all 
alike,  in  one  form  or  another,  are  represented  in  the  reli- 
gious thought  and  practice  of  the  Middle  Ages. 

All  are  represented  in  it,  but  not  all  are  equally  repre- 


THE   SOCIAL   ORGANISM  25 

sentative  of  it.  Of  the  four  attitudes  suggested  above,  it  is 
that  last  which  is  most  characteristic.  The  first  fundamental 
assumption  which  is  taken  over  by  the  sixteenth  century  is 
that  the  ultimate  standard  of  human  institutions  and  activi- 
ties is  religion.  The  architectonics  of  the  system  had  been 
worked  out  in  the  Summae  of  the  Schoolmen.  In  sharp 
contrast  to  the  modern  temper,  which  takes  the  destination 
for  granted,  and  is  thrilled  by  the  hum  of  the  engine,  me- 
dieval religious  thought  strains  every  interest  and  activity, 
by  however  arbitrary  a  compression,  into  the  service  of  a 
single  idea  The  lines  of  its  scheme  run  up  and  down,  and, 
since  purpose  is  universal  and  all-embracing,  there  is,  at 
least  in  theory,  no  room  for  eccentric  bodies  which  move  in 
their  own  private  orbit  That  purpose  is  set  by  the  divine 
plan  of  the  universe.  "The  perfect  happiness  of  man  can- 
not be  other  than  the  vision  of  the  divine  essence."  12 

Hence  all  activities  fall  within  a  single  system,  because  all, 
though  with  different  degrees  of  immediateness,  are  related 
to  a  single  end,  and  derive  their  significance  from  it.  The 
Church  in  its  wider  sense  is  the  Christian  Commonwealth, 
within  which  that  end  is  to  be  realized;  in  its  narrower 
sense  it  is  the  hierarchy  divinely  commissioned  for  its  in- 
terpretation, in  both  it  embraces  the  whole  of  life,  and  its 
authority  is  final.  Though  practice  is  perpetually  at  vari- 
ance with  theory,  there  is  no  absolute  division  between  the 
inner  and  personal  life,  which  is  "the  sphere  of  religion," 
and  the  practical  interests,  the  external  order,  the  impersonal 
mechanism,  to  which,  if  some  modern  teachers  may  be 
trusted,  religion  is  irrelevant 

There  is  no  absolute  division,  but  there  is  a  division  of 
quality.  There  are — to  use  a  modern  phrase — degrees  of 
reality.  The  distinctive  feature  of  medieval  thought  is  that 
contrasts  which  later  were  to  be  presented  as  irreconcilable 
antitheses  appear  in  it  as  differences  within  a  larger  unity, 
and  that  the  world  of  social  organization,  originating  in 
physical  necessities,  passes  by  insensible  gradations  into  that 
of  the  spirit. .  Man  shares  with  other  animals  the  necessity 
of  maintaining  and  perpetuating  his  species,  in  addition, 
as  a  natural  creature,  he  has  what  is  peculiar  to  himself, 
an  inclination  to  the  life  of  the  intellect  and  of  society — 
"to  know  the  truth  about  God  and  to  live  in  communities."  13 
These  activities,  which  form  his  life  according  to  the  law 


26  THE  MEDIEVAL  BACKGROUND 

of  nature,  may  be  regarded,  and  sometimes  are  regarded, 
as  indifferent  or  hostile  to  the  life  of  the  spirit.  But  the 
characteristic  thought  is  different.  It  is  that  of  a  synthesis. 
Vlhe  contrast  between  nature  and  grace,  between  human 
appetites  and  interests  and  religion,  is  not  absolute,  but 
relative.  It  is  a  contrast  of  matter  and  the  spirit  informing 
it,  of  stages  in  a  process,  of  preparation  and  fruition  Grace 
works  on  the  unregenerate  nature  of  man,  not  to  destroy  it, 
but  to  transform  it.  And  what  is  true  of  the  individual  is 
true  of  society.  An  attempt  is  made  to  give  it  a  new  sig- 
nificance by  relating  it  to  the  purpose  of  human  life  as 
known  by  revelation.  In  the  words  of  a  famous  (or  no- 
torious) Bull:  "The -way  of  religion  is  to  lead  the  things 
which  are  lower  to  Trle^hings  which  jare  higher  through 
the  things  which  are  interfn^iateixx^ccording  to  the  law 
of  the  universe  all  things  ar^fe^jeduced  to  order  equally 
and  immediately;  buMjb^fewest  ^Jtequgh  the  intermediate, 
the  intermediatft-*bffj!6gh  the  higher.^1  Thus  social  insti- 
tutions assume  a  character  which  may  almost  be  called  sac- 
ramental, for  they  are  the  outward  and  imperfect  expres- 
sion of  a  supreme  spiritual  reality.  Ideally  conceived,  so- 
ciety is  an  organism  of  different  grades,  and  human  activi- 
ties form  a  hierarchy  of  functions,  which  differ  in  kind  and 
in  significance,  but  each  of  which  is  of  value  on  its  own 
plane,  provided  that  it  is  governed,  however  remotely,  by 
the  end  which  is  common  to  all,VLike  the  celestial  order,  of 
which  it  is  the  dim  reflection,  sotiety  is  stable,  because  it  is 
straining  upwards: 

Anzi  e  formale  ad  esto  beato  esse 

Tenersi  dentro  alia  divma  vogha, 

Per  ch'  una  fansi  nostre  voghe  stesse 

Needless  to  say,  metaphysics,  however  sublime,  were  not 
the  daily  food  of  the  Middle  Ages,  any  more  than  of  today. 
The  fifteenth  century  saw  an  outburst  of  commercial  ac- 
tivity and  of  economic  speculation,  and  by  the  middle  of  it 
all  this  teaching  was  becoming  antiquated.  Needless  to  say, 
also,  general  ideas  cannot  be  kept  in  compartments,  and  the 
teleology  of  medieval  speculation  colored  the  interpretation 
of  common  affairs,  as  it  was  colored  by  physics  in  the 
eighteenth  century  and  by  the  idea  of  evolution  in  the  nine- 


THE    SOCIAL   ORGANISM  27 

teenth.  If  the  first  legacy  of  the  Middle  Ages  to  the  six- 
teenth century  was  the  idea  of  religion  as  embracing  all 
aspects  of  human  life,  the  second  and  third  flowed  naturally 
from  the  working  of  that  idea  in  the  economic  environ- 
ment of  the  time.  They  may  be  called,  respectively,  the 
functional  view  of  class  organization,  and  the  doctrine  of 
economic  ethics,  j 

From  the  twelfth  century  to  the  sixteenth,  from  the  work 
of  Beckett's  secretary  in  1159  to  the  work  of  Henry  VIII's 
chaplain  in  1537,  the  analogy  by  which  society  is  described 
— an  analogy  at  once  fundamental  and  commonplace — is  the 
same  1">  Invoked  in  every  economic  crisis  to  rebuke  extor- 
tion and  dissension  with  a  high  doctrine  of  social  solidarity, 
it  was  not  finally  discarded  till  the  rise  of  a  theoretical  in- 
dividualism in  England  in  the  seventeenth  century.  It  is 
that  of  the  human  body  The  gross  facts  of  the  social  order 
are  accepted  in  all  their  harshness  and  brutality.  They  are 
accepted  with  astonishing  docility,  and,  except  on  rare  oc- 
casions, there  is  no  question  of  reconstruction.  What  they 
include  is  no  trifle.  It  is  nothing  less  than  the  whole  edifice 
of  feudal  society — class  privilege,  class  oppression,  exploita- 
tion, serfdom.  But  these  things  cannot,  it  is  thought,  be 
treated  as  simply  alien  to  religion,  for  religion  is  all-compre- 
hensive. They  must  be  given  some  ethical  meaning,  must  be 
shown  to  be  the  expression  of  some  larger  plan.  The  mean- 
ing given  them  is  simple4fThe  facts  of  class  status  and  in- 
equality were  rationalized  in  the  Middle  Ages  by  a  func- 
tional theory  of  society*  as  the  facts  of  competition  were 
rationalized  in  the  eighteenth  by  the  theory  of  economic 
harmonies,  and  the  former  took  the  same  delight  in  contem- 
plating the  moral  purpose  revealed  in  social  organization 
as  the  latter  in  proving  that  to  the  curious  mechanism  of 
human  society  a  moral  purpose  was  superfluous  or  disturb- 
ing. Society,  like  the  human  body,  is  an  oiganism  composed 
of  different  members.  Each  member  has  its  own  function, 
prayer,  or  defense,  or  merchandise,  or  tilling  the  soil.  Each 
must  receive  the  means  suited  to  its  station,  and  must  claim 
no  more.  Within  classes  there  must  be  equality;  if  one  takes 
into  his  hand  the  living  of  two,  his  neighbor  will  go  short. 
Between  classes  there  must  be  inequality;  for  otherwise  a 
class  cannot  perform  its  function,  or — a  strange  thought  to 
us — enjoy  its  rights.  Peasants  must  not  encroach  on  those 


28  THE  MEDIEVAL  BACKGROUND 

above  them.  Lords  must  not  despoil  peasants.  Craftsmen 
and  merchants  must  receive  what  will  maintain  them  in  their 
calling,  and  no  morer^ 

As  a  rule  of  social  policy,  the  doctrine  was  at  once  repres- 
sive and  protective.  "There  is  degree  above  degree,  as  rea- 
son is,  and  skill  it  is  that  men  do  their  devoir  thereas  it  is 
due.  But  certes,  extortions  and  despite  of  your  underlings 
is  damnable.'' lb  As  a  philosophy  of  society,  it  attempted 
to  spiritualize  the  material  by  incorporating  it  in  a  divine 
universe,  which  should  absorb  and  transform  it  To  that 
process  of  transmutation  the  life  of  mere  money-making 
was  recalcitrant,  and  hence,  indeed,  the  stigma  attached  to 
it.  For,  in  spite  of  the  ingenuity  of  theorists,  finance  and 
trade,  the  essence  of  which  seemed  to  be,  not  service,  but  a 
mere  appetitus  dimtiarum  infinitus,  were  not  easily  inter- 
preted in  terms  of  social  function.  Comparatively  late  in- 
truders in  a  world  dominated  by  conceptions  hammered  out 
in  a  pre-commercial  age,  they  were  never  fitted  harmoni- 
ously into  the  medieval  synthesis,  and  ultimately,  when  they 
grew  to  their  full  stature,  were  to  contribute  to  its  over- 
throw. But  the  property  of  the  feudal  lord,  the  labor  of 
the  peasant  or  the  craftsman,  even  the  ferocity  of  the  war- 
rior, were  not  dismissed  as  hostile  or  indifferent  to  the  life 
of  the  spirit.  Touched  by  the  spear  of  Ithuriel,  they  were 
to  be  sublimated  into  service,  vocation  and  chivalry,  and 
the  ritual  which  surrounded  them  was  designed  to  empha- 
size that  they  had  undergone  a  re-dedication  at  the  hands  of 
religion.  Baptized  by  the  Church,  privilege  and  power  be- 
came office  and  duty 

That  the  reconciliation  was  superficial,  and  that  in  at- 
tempting it  the  Church  often  degraded  itself  without  raising 
the  world,  is  as  indisputable  as  that  its  tendency  was  to  dig- 
nify material  interests,  by  stamping  them  with  the  impress 
of  a  universal  design.  Gentlemen  took  hard  tallages  and 
oppressed  the  poor;  but  it  was  something  that  they  should 
be  told  that  their  true  function  was  "to  defend  God's  law  by 
power  of  the  world."  17  Craftsmen — the  burden  of  end- 
less sermons — worked  deceitfully,  but  it  was  perhaps  not 
wholly  without  value  that  they  should  pay  even  lip-service 
to  the  ideal  of  so  conducting  their  trade,  that  the  common 
people  should  not  be  defrauded  by  the  evil  ingenuity  of 
those  exercising  the  craft.  If  lord  and  peasant,  merchant 


THE    SOCIAL    ORGANISM  29 

and  artisan,  burgess  and  villager,  pressed  each  other  hard, 
was  it  meaningless  to  meet  their  struggles  with  an  assertion 
of  universal  solidarity,  to  which  economic  convenience  and 
economic  power  must  alike  give  way?  "The  health  of  the 
whole  commonwealth  will  be  assured  and  vigorous,  if  the 
higher  members  consider  the  lower  and  the  lower  answer  in 
like  manner  the  higher,  so  that  each  is  in  turn  a  member 
of  every  other."  18 

If  the  medieval  moralist  was  often  too  naive  in  expecting 
sound  practice  as  the  result  of  lofty  principles  alone,  he  was 
at  least  free  from  that  not  unfashionable  form  of  credulity 
which  expects  it  from  their  absence  or  from  their  opposite. 
To  say  that  the  men  to  whom  such  teaching  was  addressed 
went  out  to  rob  and  cheat  is  to  say  no  more  than  that  they 
were  men  Nor  is  it  self-evident  that  they  would  have  been 
more  likely  to  be  honest,  if  they  had  been  informed,  like 
some  of  their  descendants,  that  competition  was  designed 
by  Providence  to  provide  an  automatic  substitute  for  hon- 
esty .^Society  was  interpreted,  in  short,  not  as  the  expres- 
sion o?  economic  self-interest,  but  as  held  together  by  a 
system  of  mutual,  though  varying,  obligations  Social  well- 
being  exists,  it  was  thought,  in  so  far  as  each  class  performs 
its  functions  and  enjoys  the  rights  proportioned  thereto. 
"The  Church  is  divided  in  these  three  parts,  preachers,  an3" 
defenders,  and  laborers  ...  As  she  is  our  mother, 

so  she  is  a  body,  and  health  of  this  body  stands  in  this,  that 
one  part  of  her  answer  to  another,  after  the  same  measure 
that  Jesus  Christ  has  ordained  it  ...  Kindly  man's  hand 
helps  his  head,  and  his  eye  helps  his  foot,  and  his  foot  his 
body  .  .  and  thus  should  it  be  in  parts  of  the  Church.  .  .  . 
As  divers  parts  of  man  served  unkindly  to  man  if  one  took 
the  service  of  another  and  left  his  own  proper  work,  so  div- 
ers parts  of  the  Church  have  proper  works  to  serve  God; 
and  if  one  part  leave  his  work  that  God  has  limited  him 
and  take  work  of  another  part,  sinful  wonder  is  in  the 
Church  Surely  the  Church  shall  never  be  whole  be- 

fore proportions  of  her  parts  be  brought  again  by  this 
heavenly  leech  and  fbyl  medicine  of  men.7'19 

Speculation  does  not  develope  in  vacua.  It  echoes,  how- 
ever radical  it  is,  the  established  order.  Clearly  this  pa- 
triarchal doctrine  is  a  softened  reflection  of  the  feudal  land 
system.  Not  less  clearly  the  Church's  doctrine  of  economic 


30  THE  MEDIEVAL  BACKGROUND 

ethics  is  the  expression  of  the  conditions  of  medieval  in- 
dustry. A  religious  philosophy,  unless  it  is  frankly  to  aban- 
don nine-tenths  of  conduct  to  the  powers  of  darkness,  can- 
not admit  the  doctrine  of  a  world  of  business  and  economic 
relations  self-sufficient  and  divorced  from  ethics  and  re- 
ligion. But  the  facts  may  be  difficult  to  moralize,  or  they 
may  be  relatively  easy.  Over  a  great  part  of  Europe  in  the 
later  Middle  Ages,  the  economic  environment  was  less  in- 
tractable than  it  had  been  in  the  days  of  the  Empire  or  than 
it  is  today.  In  the  great  commercial  centers  there  was 
sometimes,  it  is  true,  a  capitalism  as  inhuman  as  any  which 
the  world  has  seen,  and  from  time  to  time  ferocious  class 
wars  between  artisans  and  merchants  20  But  outsioV  them 
trade,  industry,  the  money  market,  all  that  we  call  the  eco- 
nomic system,  was  not  a  system,  but  a  mass  of  individual 
trades  and  individual  dealings  Pecuniary  transactions  were 
a  fringe  on  a  world  of  natural  economy.  There  was  little 
mobility  or  competition  There  was  very  little  large-scale 
organization.  With  some  important  exceptions,  such  as  the 
textile  workers  of  Flanders  and  Italy,  who,  in  the  fourteenth 
century,  again  and  again  rose  in  revolt,  the  medieval  arti- 
san, especially  in  backward  countries  like  England,  was  a 
small  master  The  formation  of  temporary  organizations, 
or  "parliaments,"  of  wage-earners,  which  goes  on  in  Lon- 
don even  before  the  end  of  the  thirteenth  century,"1  and  the 
growth  of  journeymen's  associations  in  the  later  Middle 
Ages,  are  a  proof  that  the  conditions  which  produced  mod- 
ern trade  unionism  were  not  unknown  But  even  in  a  great 
city  like  Paris  the  128  gilds  which  existed  at  the  end  of  the 
thirteenth  century  appear  to  have  included  5,000  masters, 
who  employed  not  more  than  6,000  to  7,000  journeymen. 
At  Frankfurt-am-Mam  in  1387  actually  not  more  than 
750  to  800  journeymen  are  estimated  to  have  been  in  the 
service  of  1,554  masters.2" 

In  cities  of  this  kind,  with  their  freedom,  their  com- 
parative peace,  and  their  strong  corporate  feeling,  large 
enough  to  be  prolific  of  associations  and  small  enough  for 
each  man  to  know  his  neighbor,  an  ethic  of  mutual  aid  was 
not  wholly  impossible,  and  it  is  in  the  light  of  such  condi- 
tions that  the  most  characteristic  of  medieval  industrial  in- 
stitutions is  to  be  interpreted.  To  suggest  that  anything 
like  a  majority  of  medieval  workers  were  ever  members  of 


THE    SOCIAL   ORGANISM  31 

a  craft  gild  is  extravagant.  In  England,  at  any  rate,  more 
than  nine- tenths  were  peasants,  among  whom,  though 
friendly  societies  called  gilds  were  common,  there  was  nat- 
urally no  question  of  craft  organization.  Even  in  the  towns 
it  is  a  question  whether  there  was  not  a  considerable  popu- 
lation of  casual  workers — consider  only  the  number  of  un- 
skilled workers  that  must  have  been  required  as  laborers 
by  the  craftsmen  building  a  cathedral  in  the  days  before 
mechanical  cranes — who  were  rarely  organized  in  perma- 
nent societies.  To  invest  the  craft  gilds  with  a  halo  of  eco- 
nomic chivalry  is  not  less  inappropriate  They  were,  first 
and  foremost,  monopolists,  and  the  cases  in  which  their 
vested  interests  came  into  collision  with  the  consumer  were 
not  a  few  Wyclif,  with  his  almost  modern  devotion  to  the 
conception  of  a  unitary  society  over-riding  particular  in- 
terests for  the  common  good,  was  naturally  prejudiced 
against  corporations,  on  the  ground  that  they  distracted  so- 
cial unity  by  the  intrusion  of  sectarian  cupidities  and  sinis- 
ter ambitions,  but  there  was  probably  from  time  to  time 
more  than  a  little  justification  for  his  complaint  that  "all 
new  fraternities  or  gilds  made  of  men  seem  openly  to  run 
in  this  curse  [against  false  conspirators | /'  because  "they 
conspire  to  bear  up  each  other,  yea,  in  wrong,  and  oppress 
other  men  in  their  right  by  their  wit  and  power  '' 2ti  It  is 
significant  that  the  most  striking  of  the  projects  of  political 
and  social  reconstruction  produced  in  Germany  in  the  cen- 
tury before  the  Reformation  proposed  the  complete  aboli- 
tion of  gilds,  as  intolerably  corrupt  and  tyrannical.24 

There  are,  however,  monopolists  and  monopolists.  An 
age  in  which  combinations  are  not  tempted  to  pay  lip-service 
to  religion  may  do  well  to  remember  that  the  characteristic, 
after  all,  of  the  medieval  gild  was  that,  if  it  sprang  from 
economic  needs,  it  claimed,  at  least,  to  subordinate  them  to 
social  interests,  as  conceived  by  men  for  whom  the  social 
and  the  spiritual  were  inextricably  intertwined  "Tout  ce 
petit  monde  antique,"  writes  the  historian  of  French  gilds, 
"etait  fortement  imbu  des  idees  chretiennes  sur  le  juste 
salaire  et  le  juste  prix;  sans  doute  il  y  avait  alors,  comme 
aujourd'hui,  des  cupidites  et  des  convoitises;  mais  une  regie 
puissante  s'imposait  a  tous  et  d'une  maniere  generate  exi- 
geait  pour  chacun  le  pain  quotidien  promis  par  1'Evan- 
gile."  25  The  attempt  to  preserve  a  rough  equality  among 


32  THE  MEDIEVAL  BACKGROUND 

"the  good  men  of  the  mistery,"  to  check  economic  egotism 
by  insisting  that  every  brother  shall  share  his  good  fortune 
with  another  and  stand  by  his  neighbor  in  need,  to  resist 
the  encroachments  of  a  conscienceless  money-power,  to  pre- 
serve professional  standards  of  training  and  craftsmanship, 
and  to  repress  by  a  strict  corporate  discipline  the  natural 
appetite  of  each  to  snatch  special  advantages  for  himself 
to  the  injury  of  all — whether  these  things  outweigh  the  evils 
of  conservative  methods  and  corporate  exclusiveness  is  a 
question  which  each  student  will  answer  in  accordance  with 
his  own  predilections.  What  is  clear,  at  least,  is  that  both 
the  rules  of  fraternities  and  the  economic  teaching  of  the 
Church  were  prompted  by  the  problems  of  a  common  en- 
vironment. Much  that  is  now  mechanical  was  then  personal, 
intimate  and  direct,  and  there  was  little  room  for  organi- 
zation on  a  scale  too  vast  for  the  standards  that  are  applied 
to  individuals,  or  for  the  doctrine  which  silences  scruples 
and  closes  all  accounts  with  the  final  plea  of  economic  ex- 
pediency. 

Such  an  environment,  with  its  personal  economic  rela- 
tions, was  a  not  unfavorable  field  for  a  system  of  social 
ethics.  And  the  Church,  which  brought  to  its  task  the  tre- 
mendous claim  to  mediate  between  even  the  humblest  ac- 
tivity and  the  divine  purpose,  sought  to  supply  it.  True,  its 
teaching  was  violated  in  practice,  and  violated  grossly,  in 
the  very  citadel  of  Christendom  which  promulgated  it.  Con- 
temporaries were  under  no  illusion  as  to  the  reality  of  eco- 
nomic motives  in  the  Age  of  Faith.  They  had  only  to  look 
at  Rome.  From  the  middle  of  the  thirteenth  century  a 
continuous  wail  arises  against  the  iniquity  of  the  Church, 
and  its  burden  may  be  summed  up  in  one  word,  "avarice." 
At  Rome,  everything  is  for  sale  What  is  reverenced  is  the 
gospel,  not  according  to  St.  Mark,  but  according  to  the 
marks  of  silver.26 

Cum  ad  papam  venens,  habc  pro  constant!, 
Non  est  locus  paupen,  soli  iavct  danti. 

Papa,  si  rem  tangimus,  nomen  habet  a  re, 
Quicquid  habent  alii,  solus  vult  paparc , 
Vel,  si  verbum  galhcum  vis  apocopare, 
'Payez,  payez,'  dtt  le  mot,  si  vis  imoetrare.27 


THE    SOCIAL    ORGANISM  33 

The  Papacy  might  denounce  usurers,  but,  as  the  center 
of  the  most  highly  organized  administrative  system  of  the 
age,  receiving  remittances  from  all  over  Europe,  and  re- 
ceiving them  in  money  at  a  time  when  the  revenue  of  other 
Governments  still  included  personal  services  and  payments 
in  kind,  it  could  not  dispense  with  them.  Dante  put  the 
Cahorsine  money-lenders  in  hell,  but  a  Pope  gave  them  the 
title  of  ''peculiar  sons  of  the  Roman  Church. r  -tS  Grosstete 
rebuked  the  Lombard  bankers,  and  a  bishop  of  London  ex- 
pelled them,  but  papal  protection  brought  them  back.2'* 
Archbishop  Peckham,  a  few  years  later,  had  to  implore 
Pope  Nicholas  III  to  withdraw  a  threat  of  excommunica- 
tion, intended  to  compel  him  to  pay  the  usurious  interest 
demanded  by  Italian  money-lenders,  though,  as  the  arch- 
bishop justly  observed,  uby  your  Holiness's  special  man- 
date, it  would  be  my  duty  to  take  strong  measures  against 
such  lenders."  80  The  Papacy  was,  in  a  sense,  the  greatest 
financial  institution  of  the  Middle  Ages,  and,  as  its  fiscal 
system  was  elaborated,  things  became,  not  better,  but  worse. 
The  abuses  which  were  a  trickle  in  the  thirteenth  century 
were  a  torrent  in  the  fifteenth.  And  the  frailties  of  Rome, 
if  exceptional  in  their  notoriety,  can  hardly  be  regarded  as 
unique.  Priests,  it  is  from  time  to  time  complained,  engage 
in  trade  and  take  usury.31  Cathedral  chapters  lend  money 
at  high  rates  of  interest.  The  profits  of  usury,  like  those 
of  simony,  should  have  been  refused  by  churchmen,  as  hate- 
ful to  God;  but  a  bishop  of  Paris,  when  consulted  by  a 
usurer  as  to  the  salvation  of  his  soul,  instead  of  urging  res- 
titution, recommended  him  to  dedicate  his  ill-gotten  wealth 
to  the  building  of  Notre-Dame.32  "Thus,"  exclaimed  St. 
Bernard,  as  he  gazed  at  the  glories  of  Gothic  architecture, 
"wealth  is  drawn  up  by  ropes  of  wealth,  thus  money  bring- 
eth  money.  ...  0  vanity  of  vanities,  yet  no  more  vain 
than  insane!  The  Church  is  resplendent  in  her  walls,  beg- 
garly in  her  poor.  She  clothes  her  stones  in  gold,  and 
leaves  her  sons  naked.''  ^ 

The  picture  is  horrifying,  and  one  must  be  grateful  to 
those,  like  M.  Luchaire  and  Mr.  Coulton,  who  demolish 
romance.  But  the  denunciation  of  vices  implies  that  they 
are  recognized  as  vicious;  to  ignore  their  condemnation  is 
not  less  one-sided  than  to  conceal  their  existence;  and,  when 
the  halo  has  vanished  from  practice,  it  remains  to  ask  what 


34  THE  MEDIEVAL  BACKGROUND 

principles  men  valued,  and  what  standards  they  erected. 
The  economic  doctrines  elaborated  in  the  Summac  of  the 
Schoolmen,  in  which  that  question  receives  its  most  sys- 
tematic answer,  have  not  infrequently  been  dismissed  as  the 
fanciful  extravagances  of  writers  disqualified  from  throw- 
ing light  on  the  affairs  of  this  world  by  their  morbid  pre- 
occupation with  those  of  the  next.  In  reality,  whatever 
may  be  thought  of  their  conclusions,  both  the  occasion  and 
the  purpose  of  scholastic  speculations  upon  economic  ques- 
tions were  eminently  practical.  The  movement  which 
prompted  them  was  the  growth  of  trade,  of  town  life,  and 
of  a  commercial  economy,  in  a  world  whose  social  categories 
were  still  those  of  the  self-sufficing  village  and  the  feudal 
hierarchy.  The  object  of  their  authors  was  to  solve  the 
problems  to  which  such  developments  gave  rise.  It  was  to 
reconcile  the  new  contractual  relations,  which  sprang  from 
economic  expansion,  with  the  traditional  morality  expounded 
by  the  Church.  Viewed  by  posterity  as  reactionaries,  who 
damned  the  currents  of  economic  enterprise  with  an  irrel- 
evant appeal  to  Scripture  and  to  the  Fathers,  in  their  own 
age  they  were  the  pioneers  of  a  liberal  intellectual  move- 
ment. By  lifting  the  weight  of  antiquated  formulae  they 
cleared  a  space  within  the  stiff  framework  of  religious  au- 
thority for  new  and  mobile  economic  interests,  and  thus 
supplied  an  intellectual  justification  for  developments  which 
earlier  generations  would  have  condemned. 

The  mercantilist  thought  of  later  centuries  owed  a  con- 
siderable debt  to  scholastic  discussions  of  money,  prices,  and 
interest.  But  the  specific  contributions  of  medieval  writers 
to  the  technique  of  economic  theory  were  less  significant 
than  their  premises.  Their  fundamental  assumptions,  both 
of  which  were  to  leave  a  deep  imprint  on  the  social  thought 
of  the  sixteenth  and  seventeenth  centuries,  were  two:  that 
economic  interests  are  subordinate  to  the  real  business  of 
life,  which  is  salvation,  and  that  economic  conduct  is  one 
aspect  of  personal  conduct,  upon  which,  as  on  other  parts 
of  it,  the  rules  of  morality  are  binding.  Material  riches  are 
necessary;  they  have  a  secondary  importance,  since  without 
them  men  cannot  support  themselves  and  help  one  another; 
the  wise  ruler,  as  St.  Thomas  said/4  will  consider  in  found- 
ing his  State  the  natural  resources  of  the  country.  But  eco- 
nomic motives  are  suspect.  Because  they  are  powerful  ap- 


THE   SOCIAL  ORGANISM  35 

petites,  men  fear  them,  but  they  are  not  mean  enough  to  ap- 
plaud them.  Like  other  strong  passions,  what  they  need, 
it  is  thought,  is  not  a  clear  field,  but  repression.  There  is 
no  place  in  medieval  theory  for  economic  activity  which  is 
not  related  to  a  moral  end,  and  to  found  a  science  of  society 
upon  the  assumption  that  the  appetite  for  economic  gain  is  a 
constant  and  measurable  force,  to  be  accepted,  like  other 
natural  forces,  as  an  inevitable  and  self-evident  datum 
would  have  appeared  to  the  medieval  thinker  as  hardly  less 
irrational  or  less  immoral  than  to  make  the  premise  of  social 
philosophy  the  unrestrained  operation  of  such  necessary  hu- 
man attributes  as  pugnacity  or  the  sexual  instinct.  The 
outer  is  ordained  for  the  sake  of  the  inner;  economic  goods 
are  instrumental — sicut  quaedam  admimcula,  quibus  ad- 
juvamur  ad  tcndendum  in  beatitudincm.  "It  is  lawful  to 
desire  temporal  blessings,  not  putting  them  in  the  first  place, 
as  though  setting  up  our  rest  in  them,  but  regarding  them 
as  aids  to  blessedness,  inasmuch  as  they  support  our  cor- 
poral life  and  serve  as  instruments  for  acts  of  virtue." 35 
Riches,  as  St  Antonino  says,  exist  for  man,  not  man  for 
riches. 

At  every  turn,  therefore,  there  are  limits,  restrictions, 
warnings  against  allowing  economic  interests  to  interfere 
with  serious  affairs.  It  is  right  for  a  man  to  seek  such 
wealth  as  is  necessary  for  a  livelihood  in  his  station.  To 
seek  more  is  not  enterprise,  but  avarice,  and  avarice  is  a 
deadly  sin.  Trade  is  legitimate;  the  different  resources  of 
different  countries  show  that  it  was  intended  by  Providence. 
But  it  is  a  dangerous  business.  A  man  must  be  sure  that 
he  carries  it  on  for  the  public  benefit,  and  that  the  profits 
which  he  takes  are  no  more  than  the  wages  of  his  labor. 
Private  property  is  a  necessary  institution,  at  least  in  a 
fallen  world;  men  work  more  and  dispute  less  when  goods 
are  private  than  when  they  are  common.  But  it  is  to  be 
tolerated  as  a  concession  to  human  frailty,  not  applauded  as 
desirable  in  itself,  the  ideal — if  only  man's  nature  could 
rise  to  it — is  communism.  "Communis  enim,"  wrote  Gra- 
tian  in  his  decretum,  "usus  omnium,  quae  sunt  in  hoc  mundo, 
omnibus  hominibus  esse  debuit."  3b  At  best,  indeed,  the  es- 
tate is  somewhat  encumbered.  It  must  be  legitimately  ac- 
quired. It  must  be  in  the  largest  possible  number  of  hands. 
It  must  provide  for  the  support  of  the  poor.  Its  use  must 


36  THE  MEDIEVAL  BACKGROUND 

as  far  as  practicable  be  common.  Its  owners  must  be  ready 
to  share  it  with  those  who  need,  even  if  they  are  not  in  ac- 
tual destitution.  Such  were  the  conditions  which  com- 
mended themselves  to  an  archbishop  of  the  business  capital 
of  fifteenth-century  Europe.37  There  have  been  ages  in 
which  they  would  have  been  described,  not  as  a  justification 
of  property,  but  as  a  revolutionary  assault  on  it.  For  to  de- 
fend the  property  of  the  peasant  and  small  master  is  neces- 
sarily to  attack  that  of  the  monopolist  and  usurer,  which 
grows  by  devouring  it. 

The  assumption  on  which  all  this  body  of  doctrine  rested 
was  simple.  It  was  that  the  danger  of  economic  interests 
increased  in  direct  proportion  to  the  prominence  of  the  pe- 
cuniary motives  associated  with  them.  Labor — the  common 
lot  of  mankind — is  necessary  and  honorable ;  trade  is  neces- 
sary, but  perilous  to  the  soul;  finance,  if  not  immoral,  is  at 
best  sordid  and  at  worst  disreputable.  This  curious  inver- 
sion of  the  social  values  of  more  enlightened  ages  is  best 
revealed  in  medieval  discussions  of  the  ethics  of  commerce 
The  severely  qualified  tolerance  extended  to  the  trader  was 
partly,  no  doubt,  a  literary  convention  derived  from  clas- 
sical models;  it  was  natural  that  Aquinas  should  laud  the 
State  which  had  small  need  of  merchants  because  it  could 
meet  its  needs  from  the  produce  of  its  own  soil;  had  not  the 
Philosopher  himself  praised  aurapXeia.  But  it  was  a  con- 
vention which  coincided  with  a  vital  element  in  medieval 
social  theory,  and  struck  a  responsive  note  in  wide  sections 
of  medieval  society.  It  is  not  disputed,  of  course,  that  trade 
is  indispensable;  the  merchant  supplements  the  deficiencies 
of  one  country  with  the  abundance  of  another.  If  there 
were  no  private  traders,  argued  Duns  Scotus,  whose  indul- 
gence was  less  carefully  guarded,  the  governor  would  have 
to  engage  them.  Their  profits,  therefore,  are  legitimate, 
and  they  may  include,  not  only  the  livelihood  appropriate 
to  the  trader's  status,  but  payment  for  labor,  skill,  and  risk  !S 

The  defence,  if  adequate,  was  somewhat  embarrassing 
For  why  should  a  defence  be  required?  The  insistence  that 
trade  is  not  positively  sinful  conveys  a  hint  that  the  practices 
of  traders  may  be,  at  least,  of  dubious  propriety.  And  so,  in 
the  eyes  of  most  medieval  thinkers,  they  are.  Summe 
periculosa  est  venditioms  et  emptionis  negotiation  The 
explanation  of  that  attitude  lay  partlv  in  the  facts  of  con- 


THE   SOCIAL  ORGANISM  37 

temporary  economic  organization.  The  economy  of  the 
medieval  borough — consider  only  its  treatment  of  food  sup- 
plies and  prices — was  one  in  which  consumption  held  some- 
what the  same  primacy  in  the  public  mind,  as  the  undisputed 
arbiter  of  economic  effort,  as  the  nineteenth  century  attached 
to  profits  The  merchant  pure  and  simple,  though  con- 
venient to  the  Crown,  for  whom  he  collected  taxes  and  pro- 
vided loans,  and  to  great  establishments  such  as  monas- 
teries, whose  wool  he  bought  in  bulk,  enjoyed  the  double 
unpopularity  of  an  alien  and  a  parasite  The  best  practical 
commentary  on  the  tepid  indulgence  extended  by  theorists 
to  the  trader  is  the  network  of  restrictions  with  which 
medieval  policy  surrounded  his  activities,  the  recurrent 
storms  of  public  indignation  against  him,  and  the  ruthless- 
ness  with  which  boroughs  suppressed  the  middleman  who 
intei  vened  between  consumer  and  producer. 

Apart,  however,  from  the  color  which  it  took  from  its 
environment,  medieval  social  theory  had  reasons  of  its  own 
for  holding  that  business,  as  distinct  from  labor,  required 
some  special  justification  The  suspicion  of  economic  mo- 
tives had  been  one  of  the  earliest  elements  in  the  social 
teaching  of  the  Church,  and  was  to  survive  till  Calvinism 
endowed  the  life  of  economic  enterprise  with  a  new  sancti- 
fication.  In  medieval  philosophy  the  ascetic  tradition,  which 
condemned  all  commerce  as  the  sphere  of  iniquity,  was  soft- 
ened by  a  recognition  of  practical  necessities,  but  it  was  not 
obliterated,  and,  if  reluctant  to  condemn,  it  was  insistent 
to  warn.  For  it  was  of  the  essence  of  trade  to  drag  into  a 
position  of  solitary  prominence  the  acquisitive  appetites;  and 
towards  those  appetites,  which  to  most  modern  thinkers 
have  seemed  the  one  sure  social  dynamic,  the  attitude  of 
the  medieval  theorist  was  that  of  one  who  holds  a  wolf  by 
the  ears  The  craftsman  labors  for  his  living;  he  seeks 
what  is  sufficient  to  support  him,  and  no  more.  The  mer- 
chant aims,  not  merely  at  livelihood,  but  at  profit.  The  tra- 
ditional distinction  was  expressed  in  the  words  of  Gratian: 
"Whosoever  buys  a  thing,  not  that  he  may  sell  it  whole  and 
unchanged,  but  that  it  may  be  a  material  for  fashioning 
something,  he  is  no  merchant.  But  the  man  who  buys  it 
in  order  that  he  may  gain  by  selling  it  again  unchanged 
and  as  he  bought  it,  that  man  is  of  the  buyers  and  sellers 
who  are  cast  forth  from  God's  temple."  40  By  very  defini- 


38  THE  MEDIEVAL  BACKGROUND 

tion  a  man  who  "buys  in  order  that  he  may  sell  dearer,"  the 
trader  is  moved  by  an  inhuman  concentration  on  his  own 
pecuniary  interest,  unsoftened  by  any  tincture  of  public 
spirit  or  private  charity.  He  turns  what  should  be  a  means 
into  an  end,  and  his  occupation,  therefore,  "is  justly  con- 
demned, since,  regarded  in  itself,  it  serves  the  lust  of 
gain."  41 

The  dilemma  presented  by  a  form  of  enterprise  at  once 
perilous  to  the  soul  and  essential  to  society  was  revealed  in 
the  solution  most  commonly  propounded  for  it.  It  was  to 
treat  profits  as  a  particular  case  of  wages,  with  the  quali- 
fication that  gains  in  excess  of  a  reasonable  remuneration 
for  the  merchant's  labor  were,  though  not  illegal,  reprehen- 
sible as  turpe  lucrum.  The  condition  of  the  trader's  exon- 
eration is  that  "he  seeks  gain,  not  as  an  end,  but  as  the  wages 
of  his  labor."  42  Theoretically  convenient,  the  doctrine  was 
difficult  of  application,  for  evidently  it  implied  the  accept- 
ance of  what  the  sedate  irony  of  Adam  Smith  was  later  to 
describe  as  "an  affectation  not  very  common  among  mer- 
chants." But  the  motives  which  prompted  it  were  character- 
istic. The  medieval  theorist  condemned  as  a  sin  precisely 
that  effort  to  achieve  a  continuous  and  unlimited  increase 
in  material  wealth  which  modern  societies  applaud  as  a 
quality,  and  the  vices  for  which  he  reserved  his  most  mer- 
ciless denunciations  were  the  more  refined  and  subtle  of  the 
economic  virtues.  "He  who  has  enough  to  satisfy  his 
wants,"  wrote  a  Schoolman  of  the  fourteenth  century,  "and 
nevertheless  ceaselessly  labors  to  acquire  riches,  either  in 
order  to  obtain  a  higher  social  position,  or  that  subsequently 
he  may  have  enough  to  live  without  labor,  or  that  his  sons 
may  become  men  of  wealth  and  importance — all  such  are  in- 
cited by  a  damnable  avarice,  sensuality,  or  pride  "  45  Two 
and  a  half  centuries  later,  in  the  midst  of  a  revolution  in  the 
economic  and  spiritual  environment,  Luther,  in  even  more 
unmeasured  language,  was  to  say  the  same.44  The  essence 
of  the  argument  was  that  payment  may  properly  be  de- 
manded by  the  craftsmen  who  make  the  goods,  or  by  the 
merchants  who  transport  them,  for  both  labor  in  their  voca- 
tion and  serve  the  common  need.  The  unpardonable  sin  is 
that  of  the  speculator  or  the  middleman,  who  snatches  pri- 
vate gain  by  the  exploitation  of  public  necessities.  The  true 


THE    SIN    OF   AVARICE  39 

descendant  of  the  doctrines  of  Aquinas  is  the  labor  theory 
of  value.   The  last  of  the  Schoolmen  was  Karl  Marx. 

II     THE  SIN  OF  AVARICE 

If  such  ideas  were  to  be  more  than  generalities,  they  re- 
quired to  be  translated  into  terms  of  the  particular  transac- 
tions by  which  trade  is  conducted  and  property  acquired. 
Their  practical  expression  was  the  body  of  economic  casuis- 
try, in  which  the  best-known  elements  are  the  teaching  with 
regard  to  the  just  price  and  the  prohibition  of  usury. 
These  doctrines  sprang  as  much  from  the  popular  conscious- 
ness of  the  plain  facts  of  the  economic  situation  as  from 
the  theorists  who  expounded  them.  The  innumerable  fa- 
bles of  the  usurer  who  was  prematurely  carried  to  hell,  or 
whose  money  turned  to  withered  leaves  in  his  strong  box, 
or  who  (as  the  scrupulous  recorder  remarks),  "about  the 
year  1240, "  on  entering  a  church  to  be  married,  was  crushed 
by  a  stone  figure  falling  from  the  porch,  which  proved  by 
the  grace  of  God  to  be  a  carving  of  another  usurer  and  his 
money-bags  being  carried  off  by  the  devil,  are  more  illum- 
inating than  the  refinements  of  lawyers  4~ 

On  these  matters,  as  the  practice  of  borough  and  manor, 
as  well  as  of  national  governments,  shows,  the  Church  was 
preaching  to  the  converted,  and  to  dismiss  Its  teaching  on 
economic  ethics  as  the  pious  rhetoric  of  professional  moral- 
ists is  to  ignore  the  fact  that  precisely  similar  ideas  were 
accepted  in  circles  which  could  not  be  suspected  of  any  un- 
natuial  squeamishness  as  to  the  arts  by  which  men  grow 
rich.  The  best  commentary  on  ecclesiastical  doctrines  as 
to  usury  and  prices  is  the  secular  legislation  on  similar  sub- 
jects, for,  down  at  least  to  the  middle  of  the  sixteenth  cen- 
tury, their  leading  ideas  were  reflected  in  it.  Plain  men 
might  curse  'the  chicanery  of  ecclesiastical  lawyers,  and 
gilds  and  boroughs  might  forbid  their  members  to  plead  be- 
fore ecclesiastical  courts;  but  the  rules  which  they  them- 
selves made  for  the  conduct  of  business  had  more  than  a 
flavor  of  the  canon  law.  Florence  was  the  financial  capital 
of  medieval  Europe;  but  even  at  Florence  the  secular  au- 
thorities fined  bankers  right  and  left  for  usury  in  the  middle 
of  the  fourteenth  century,  and,  fifty  years  later,  first  prohib- 
ited credit  transactions  altogether,  and  then  imported  Jews 


40  THE  MEDIEVAL  BACKGROUND 

to  conduct  a  business  forbidden  to  Christians.46  Cologne  was 
one  of  the  greatest  of  commercial  entrepots,  but,  when  its 
successful  business  man  came  to  make  his  will,  he  remem- 
bered that  trade  was  perilous  to  the  soul  and  avarice  a  deadly 
sin,  and  offered  what  atonement  he  could  by  directing  his 
sons  to  make  restitution  and  to  follow  some  less  dangerous 
occupation  than  that  of  the  merchant.47  The  burgesses  of 
Coventry  fought  the  Prior  over  a  question  of  common  rights 
for  the  best  part  of  a  century;  but  the  Court  Leet  of  that 
thriving  business  city  put  usury  on  a  par  with  adultery  and 
fornication,  and  decreed  that  no  usurer  could  become  mayor, 
councillor,  or  master  of  the  gild  4S  It  was  not  that  laymen 
were  unnaturally  righteous;  it  was  not  that  the  Church  was 
all-powerful,  though  its  teaching  wound  into  men's  minds 
through  a  hundred  channels,  and  survived  as  a  sentiment 
long  after  it  was  repudiated  as  a  command  It  was  that  the 
facts  of  the  economic  situation  imposed  themselves  irresist- 
ibly on  both  In  reality,  there  was  no  sharp  collision  between 
the  doctrine  of  the  Church  and  the  public  policy  of  the 
world  of  business — its  individual  practice  was,  of  course, 
another  matter — because  both  were  formed  by  the  same  en- 
vironment, and  accepted  the  same  broad  assumptions  as  to 
social  expediency. 

The  economic  background  of  it  all  was  very  simple.  The 
medieval  consumer — we  can  sympathize  with  him  today 
more  easily  than  in  1914 — is  like  a  traveller  condemned  to 
spend  his  life  at  a  station  hotel.  He  occupies  a  tied  house 
and  is  at  the  mercy  of  the  local  baker  and  brewer  Monop- 
oly is  inevitable.  Indeed,  a  great  part  of  medieval  industry 
is  a  system  of  organized  monopolies,  endowed  with  a  public 
status,  which  must  be  watched  with  jealous  eyes  to  see  that 
they  do  not  abuse  their  powers.  It  is  a  society  of  small  mas- 
ters and  peasant  farmers.  Wages  are  not  a  burning  question, 
for,  except  in  the  great  industrial  centers  of  Italy  and  Flan- 
ders, the  permanent  wage-earning  class  is  small.  Usury  is, 
as  it  is  today  in  similar  circumstances  For  loans  are  made 
largely  for  consumption,  not  for  production.  The  farmer 
whose  harvest  fails  or  whose  beasts  die,  or  the  artisan  who 
loses  money,  must  have  credit,  seed-corn,  cattle,  raw  mate- 
rials, and  his  distress  is  the  money-lender's  opportunity. 
Naturally,  there  is  a  passionate  popular  sentiment  against 
the  engrosser  who  holds  a  town  to  ransom,  the  monopolist 


THE    SIN    OF   AVARICE  41 

who  brings  the  livings  of  many  into  the  hands  of  one,  the 
money-lender  who  takes  advantage  of  his  neighbor's  neces- 
sities to  get  a  lien  on  their  land  and  foreclose.  "The  usurer 
would  not  loan  to  men  these  goods,  but  if  he  hoped  winning, 
that  he  loves  more  than  charity.  Many  other  sins  be  more 
than  this  usury,  but  for  this  men  curse  and  hate  it  more 
than  other  sin  "  4q 

No  one  who  examines  the  cases  actually  heard  by  the 
courts  in  the  later  Middle  Ages  will  think  that  resentment 
surprising,  for  they  throw  a  lurid  light  on  the  possibilities 
of  commercial  immorality  r'°  Among  the  peasants  and  small 
masters  who  composed  the  mass  of  the  population  in  me- 
dieval England,  borrowing  and  lending  were  common,  and  it 
was  with  reference  to  their  petty  transactions,  not  to  the 
world  of  high  finance,  that  the  traditional  attitude  towards 
the  money-lender  had  been  crystallized.  It  was  natural  that 
ujuetta  [who]  is  a  usuress  and  sells  at  a  dearer  rate  for  ac- 
commodation/' and  John  the  Chaplain,  qui  est  usurarius 
maximns,''1  should  be  regarded  as  figures  at  once  too  scan- 
dalous to  be  tolerated  by  their  neighbors  and  too  convenient 
to  be  altogether  suppressed.  The  Church  accepts  this  pop- 
ular sentiment,  gives  it  a  religious  significance,  and  crystal- 
lizes it  in  a  system,  in  which  economic  morality  is  preached 
from  the  pulpit,  emphasized  in  the  confessional,  and  en- 
iorced,  in  the  last  resource,  through  the  courts. 

The  philosophical  basis  of  it  is  the  conception  of  natural 
law.  ''Every  law  framed  by  man  bears  the  character  of  a  law 
exactly  to  that  extent  to  which  it  is  derived  from  the  law  of 
nature.  But  if  on  any  point  it  is  in  conflict  with  the  law  of 
nature,  it  at  once  ceases  to  be  a  law;  it  is  a  mere  perversion 
of  law  "  r>J  The  plausible  doctrine  of  compensations,  of  the 
long  run,  of  the  self-correcting  mechanism,  has  not  yet  been 
invented  The  idea  of  a  law  of  nature — of  natural  justice 
which  ought  to  find  expression  in  positive  law,  but  which  is 
not  exhausted  in  it — supplies  an  ideal  standard  by  which  the 
equity  of  particular  relations  can  be  measured.  The  most 
fundamental  difference  between  medieval  and  modern  eco- 
nomic thought  consists,  indeed,  in  the  fact  that,  whereas  the 
latter  normally  refers  to  economic  expediency,  however  it 
may  be  interpreted,  for  the  justification  of  any  particular  ac- 
tion, policy,  or  system  of  organization,  the  former  starts  from 
the  position  that  there  is  a  moral  authority  to  which  con- 


42  THE  MEDIEVAL  BACKGROUND 

siderations  of  economic  expediency  must  be  subordinated. 
The  practical  application  of  this  conception  is  the  attempt 
to  try  every  transaction  by  a  rule  of  right,  which  is  largely, 
though  not  wholly,  independent  of  the  fortuitous  combina- 
tions of  economic  circumstances.  No  man  must  ask  more 
than  the  price  fixed,  either  by  public  authorities,  or,  failing 
that,  by  common  estimation.  True,  prices  even  so  will  vary 
with  scarcity;  for,  with  all  their  rigor,  theologians  are  not  so 
impracticable  as  to  rule  out  the  effect  of  changing  supplies. 
But  they  will  not  vary  with  individual  necessity  or  individ- 
ual opportunity  The  bugbear  is  the  man  who  uses,  or  even 
creates,  a  temporary  shortage,  the  man  who  makes  money 
out  of  the  turn  of  the  market,  the  man  who,  as  Wyclif  says, 
must  be  wicked,  or  he  could  not  have  been  poor  yesterday 
and  rich  today. 5i 

The  formal  theory  of  the  just  price  went,  it  is  true,  through 
a  considerable  development  The  dominant  conception  of 
Aquinas — that  prices,  though  they  will  vary  with  the  vary- 
ing conditions  of  different  markets,  should  correspond  with 
the  labor  and  costs  of  the  producer,  as  the  proper  basis  of 
the  comrnums  eslimatio,  conformity  with  which  was  the 
safeguard  against  extortion— was  qualified  by  subsequent 
writers.  Several  Schoolmen  of  the  fourteenth  century  em- 
phasized the  subjective  element  in  the  common  estimation, 
insisted  that  the  essence  of  value  was  utility,  and  drew  the 
conclusion  that  a  fair  price  was  most  likely  to  be  reached 
under  freedom  of  contract,  since  the  mere  fact  that  a  bar- 
gain had  been  struck  showed  that  both  parties  were  satis- 
fied/'4 In  the  fifteenth  century  St.  Antonino,  who  wrote  with 
a  highly  developed  commercial  civilization  beneath  his  eyes, 
endeavored  to  effect  a  synthesis,  in  which  the  principle  of 
the  traditional  doctrine  should  be  observed,  while  the  neces- 
sary play  should  be  left  to  economic  motives  After  a  subtle 
analysis  of  the  conditions  affecting  value,  he  concluded  that 
the  fairness  of  a  price  could  at  best  be  a  matter  only  of 
"probability  and  conjecture,"  since  it  would  vary  with  places, 
periods  and  persons.  His  practical  contribution  was  to  intro- 
duce a  new  elasticity  into  the  whole  conception  by  distin- 
guishing three  grades  of  prices — a  gradus  plus,  discretus, 
and  rigidus.  A  seller  who  exceeded  the  price  fixed  by  more 
than  50  per  cent,  was  bound,  he  argued,  to  make  restitution, 
and  even  a  smaller  departure  from  it,  if  deliberate,  required 


THE    SIN    OF   AVARICE  43 

atonement  in  the  shape  of  alms.  But  accidental  lapses  were 
venial,  and  there  was  a  debatable  ground  within  which  prices 
might  move  without  involving  sin.35 

This  conclusion,  with  its  recognition  of  the  impersonal 
forces  of  the  market,  was  the  natural  outcome  of  the  intense 
economic  activity  of  the  later  Middle  Ages,  and  evidently 
contained  the  seeds  of  an  intellectual  revolution.  The  fact 
that  it  should  have  begun  to  be  expounded  as  early  as  the 
middle  of  the  fourteenth  century  is  a  reminder  that  the  eco- 
nomic thought  of  Schoolmen  contained  elements  much  more 
various  and  much  more  modern  than  is  sometimes  suggested. 
But  the  characteristic  doctrine  was  different.  It  was  that 
which  insisted  on  the  just  price  as  the  safeguard  against 
extortion.  "To  leave  the  prices  of  goods  at  the  discretion  of 
the  sellers  is  to  give  rein  to  the  cupiditv  which  goads  almost 
all  of  them  to  seek  excessive  gain  "  Prices  must  be  such, 
and  no  more  than  such,  as  will  enable  each  man  to  "have 
the  necessaries  of  life  suitable  for  his  station  "  The  most 
desirable  course  is  that  they  should  be  fixed  by  public  offi- 
cials, after  making  an  enquiry  into  the  supplies  available 
and  framing  an  estimate  of  the  requirements  of  different 
classes.  Failing  that,  the  individual  must  fix  prices  for  him- 
self, guided  by  a  consideration  of  "what  he  must  charge  in 
order  to  maintain  his  position,  and  nourish  himself  suitably 
in  it,  and  by  a  reasonable  estimate  of  his  expenditure  and 
labor  "  r><)  If  the  latter  recommendation  was  a  counsel  of  per- 
fection, the  former  was  almost  a  platitude  It  was  no  more 
than  an  energetic  mayor  would  carry  out  before  breakfast. 

No  man,  again,  may  charge  money  for  a  loan  He  may,  of 
course,  take  the  profits  of  partnership,  provided  that  he  takes 
the  partner's  risks.  He  may  buy  a  rent-charge,  for  the  fruits 
of  the  earth  are  produced  by  nature,  not  wrung  from  man. 
He  may  demand  compensation — intcresse — if  he  is  not  re- 
paid the  principal  at  the  time  stipulated.  He  may  ask  pay- 
ment corresponding  to  any  loss  he  incurs  or  gain  he  foregoes. 
He  may  purchase  an  annuity,  for  the  payment  is  contingent 
and  speculative,  not  certain.  It  is  no  usury  when  John  Deve- 
neys,  who  has  borrowed  £19  16s.,  binds  himself  to  pay  a 
penalty  of  £40  in  the  event  of  failure  to  restore  the  principal, 
for  this  is  compensation  for  damages  incurred;  or  when 
Geoffrey  de  Eston  grants  William  de  Burwode  three  marks  of 
silver  in  return  for  an  annual  rent  of  six  shillings,  for  this  is 


44  THE  MEDIEVAL  BACKGROUND 

the  purchase  of  a  rent-charge,  not  a  loan;  or  when  James  le 
Reve  of  London  advances  £100  to  Robert  de  Bree  of  Dublin, 
merchant,  with  which  to  trade  for  two  years  in  Ireland,  for 
this  is  a  partnership ;  or  when  the  priority  of  Worcester  sells 
annuities  for  a  capital  sum  paid  down  r>T  What  remained  to 
the  end  unlawful  was  that  which  appears  in  modern  eco- 
nomic text-books  as  "pure  interest1' —  interest  as  a  fixed  pay- 
ment stipulated  in  advance  for  a  loan  of  money  or  wares 
without  risk  to  the  lender  uUsura  est  ex  mutuo  lucrum 
pacto  debitum  vel  exactum  .  .  quidquid  sorti  accedit, 
subaudi  per  pactum  vel  exactionem,  usura  est,  quodcunque 
nomen  sibi  imponat  "  ~'s  The  emphasis  was  on  pactum  The 
essence  of  usury  was  that  it  was  certain,  and  that,  whether 
the  borrower  gained  or  lost,  the  usurer  took  his  pound  of 
flesh  Medieval  opinion,  which  has  no  objection  to  rent  or 
profits,  provided  that  they  are  reasonable — for  is  not  every 
one  in  a  small  way  a  profit-maker? — has  no  mercy  for  the 
debenture-holder  His  crime  is  that  he  takes  a  payment  for 
money  which  is  fixed  and  certain,  and  such  a  payment  is 
usury. 

The  doctrine  was,  of  course,  more  complex  and  more 
subtle  than  a  bald  summary  suggests.  With  the  growth  of 
the  habit  of  investment,  of  a  market  for  capital,  and  of  new 
forms  of  economic  enterprise  such  as  insurance  and  exchange 
business,  theory  became  steadily  more  elaborate  and  schools 
more  sharply  divided.  The  precise  meaning  and  scope  of  the 
indulgence  extended  to  the  purchase  of  rent-charges  produced 
one  controversy,  the  foreign  exchanges  another,  the  develop- 
ment of  Monts  dc  Pietc  a  third  Even  before  the  end  of  the 
fourteenth  century  there  had  been  writers  who  argued  that 
interest  was  the  remuneration  of  the  services  rendered  by 
the  lender,  and  who  pointed  out  (though  apparently  they 
did  not  draw  the  modern  corollary)  that  present  are  more 
valuable  than  future  goods  V)  But  on  the  iniquity  of  pay- 
ment merely  for  the  act  of  lending,  theological  opinion, 
whether  liberal  or  conservative,  was  unanimous,  and  its  mod- 
ern interpreter,60  who  sees  in  its  indulgence  to  intercsse 
the  condonation  of  interest,  would  have  created  a  scandal  in 
theological  circles  in  any  age  before  that  of  Calvin  To  take 
usury  is  contrary  to  Scripture;  it  is  contrary  to  Aristotle; 
it  is  contrary  to  nature,  for  it  is  to  live  without  labor,  it  is 
to  sell  time,  which  belongs  to  God,  for  the  advantage  of 


THE    SIN    OF    AVARICE  45 

wicked  men;  it  is  to  rob  those  who  use  the  money  lent,  and 
to  whom,  since  they  make  it  profitable,  the  profits  should 
belong,  it  is  unjust  in  itself,  for  the  benefit  of  the  loan  to 
the  borrower  cannot  exceed  the  value  of  the  principal  sum 
lent  him;  it  is  in  defiance  of  sound  juristic  principles,  for 
when  a  loan  of  money  is  made,  the  property  in  the  thing 
lent  passes  to  the  borrower,  and  why  should  the  creditor 
demand  payment  from  a  man  who  is  merely  using  what  is 
now  his  own? 

The  part  played  by  authority  in  all  this  is  obvious.  There 
were  the  texts  in  Exodus  and  Leviticus;  there  was  Luke  vi. 
35 — apparently  a  mistranslation;  there  was  a  passage  in  the 
Politics,  which  some  now  say  was  mistranslated  also.01  But 
practical  considerations  contributed  more  to  the  doctrine 
than  is  sometimes  supposed.  Its  character  had  been  given  it 
in  an  age  in  which  most  loans  were  not  part  of  a  credit  sys- 
tem, but  an  exceptional  expedient,  and  in  which  it  could  be 
said  that  "he  who  borrows  is  always  under  stress  of  neces- 
sity." If  usury  were  general,  it  was  argued,  "men  would  not 
give  thought  to  the  cultivation  of  their  land,  except  when 
they  could  do  nought  else,  and  so  there  would  be  so  great 
a  famine  that  all  the  poor  would  die  of  hunger;  for  even  if 
they  could  get  land  to  cultivate,  they  would  not  be  able  to 
get  the  beasts  and  implements  for  cultivating  it,  since  the 
poor  themselves  would  not  have  them,  and  the  rich,  for  the 
sake  both  of  profit  and  of  security,  would  put  their  money 
into  usury  rather  than  into  smaller  and  more  risky  invest- 
ments." 62  The  man  who  used  these  arguments  was  not  an 
academic  dreamer.  He  was  Innocent  IV,  a  consummate  man 
of  business,  a  believer,  even  to  excess,  in  Rcalpolitik,  and 
one  of  the  ablest  statesmen  of  his  day. 

True,  the  Church  could  not  dispense  with  commercial 
wickedness  in  high  places.  It  was  too  convenient.  The  dis- 
tinction between  pawnbroking,  which  is  disreputable,  and 
high  finance,  which  is  eminently  honorable  was  as  familiar 
in  the  Age  of  Faith  as  in  the  twentieth  century;  and  no 
reasonable  judgment  of  the  medieval  denunciation  of  usury 
is  possible,  unless  it  is  remembered  that  whole  ranges  of 
financial  business  escaped  from  it  almost  altogether.  It  was 
rarely  applied  to  the  large-scale  transactions  of  kings,  feudal 
magnates,  bishops  and  abbots.  Their  subjects,  squeezed  to 
pay  a  foreign  money-lender,  might  grumble  or  rebel,  but,  if 


46  THE  MEDIEVAL  BACKGROUND 

an  Edward  TIT  or  a  Count  of  Champagne  was  in  the  hands 
of  financiers,  who  could  bring  either  debtor  or  creditor  to 
book?  It  was  even  more  rarely  applied  to  the  Papacy  itself, 
Popes  regularly  employed  the  international  banking  houses 
of  the  day,  with  a  singular  indifference,  as  was  frequently 
complained,  to  the  morality  of  their  business  methods,  took 
them  under  their  special  protection,  and  sometimes  enforced 
the  payment  of  debts  by  the  threat  of  excommunication.  As 
a  rule,  in  spite  of  some  qualms,  the  international  money- 
market  escaped  from  it ,  in  the  fourteenth  century  Italy  was 
full  of  banking-houses  doing  foreign  exchange  business  in 
every  commercial  center  from  Constantinople  to  London, 
and  in  the  great  fairs,  such  as  those  of  Champagne,  a  spe- 
cial period  was  regularly  set  aside  for  the  negotiation  of 
loans  and  the  settlement  of  debts  ° 5 

It  was  not  that  transactions  of  this  type  were  expressly 
excepted,  on  the  contrary,  each  of  them  from  time  to  time 
evoked  the  protests  of  moralists.  Nor  was  it  mere  hypocrisy 
which  caused  the  traditional  doctrine  to  be  repeated  by 
writers  who  were  perfectly  well  aware  that  neither  commerce 
nor  government  could  be  carried  on  without  credit  It  was 
that  the  whole  body  of  intellectual  assumptions  and  practical 
interests,  on  which  the  prohibition  of  usury  was  based,  had 
reference  to  a  quite  different  order  of  economic  activities 
from  that  represented  by  loans  from  great  banking-houses 
to  the  merchants  and  potentates  who  were  their  clients  Its 
object  was  simple  and  direct — to  prevent  the  well-to-do 
money-lender  from  exploiting  the  necessities  of  the  peasant 
or  the  craftsman;  its  categories,  which  were  quite  appro- 
priate to  that  type  of  transaction,  were  those  of  personal 
morality.  It  was  in  these  commonplace  dealings  among  small 
men  that  oppression  was  easiest  and  its  results  most  pitiable 
It  was  for  them  that  the  Church's  scheme  of  economic  ethics 
had  been  worked  out,  and  with  reference  to  them,  though 
set  at  naught  in  high  places,  it  was  meant  to  be  enforced 
for  it  was  part  of  Christian  charity. 

It  was  enforced  partly  by  secular  authorities,  partly,  in 
so  far  as  the  rivalry  of  secular  authorities  would  permit  it, 
by  the  machinery  of  ecclesiastical  discipline.  The  ecclesias- 
tical legislation  on  the  subject  of  usury  has  been  so  often 
analyzed  that  it  is  needless  to  do  more  than  allude  to  it. 
Early  Councils  had  forbidden  usury  to  be  taken  by  the 
clergy.64  The  Councils  of  the  twelfth  and  thirteenth  centuries 


THE    SIN    OF   AVARICE  47 

forbid  it  to  be  taken  by  clergy  or  laity,  and  lay  down  rules 
for  dealing  with  offenders.  Clergy  who  lend  money  to  persons 
in  need,  take  their  possession  in  pawn,  and  receive  profits 
beyond  the  capital  sum  lent,  are  to  be  deprived  of  their 
office.Gr>  Manifest  usurers  are  not  to  be  admitted  to  com- 
munion or  Christian  burial;  their  offerings  are  not  to  be 
accepted;  and  ecclesiastics  who  fail  to  punish  them  are  to 
be  suspended  until  they  make  satisfaction  to  their  bishop.66 
The  high-water  mark  of  the  ecclesiastical  attack  on  usury 
was  probably  reached  in  the  legislation  of  the  Councils  of 
Lyons  (1274)  and  of  Vienne  (1312).  The  former  re-enacted 
the  measures  laid  down  by  the  third  Lateran  Council  (1175), 
and  supplemented  them  by  rules  which  virtually  made  the 
money-lender  an  outlaw.  No  individual  or  society,  under 
pain  of  excommunication  or  interdict,  was  to  let  houses  to 
usurers,  but  was  to  expel  them  (had  they  been  admitted) 
within  three  months.  They  were  to  be  refused  confession, 
absolution  and  Christian  burial  until  they  had  made  resti- 
tution, and  their  wills  were  to  be  invalid/'7  The  legislation 
of  the  Council  of  Vienne  was  even  more  sweeping  Declaring 
that  it  has  learned  with  dismay  that  there  were  communities 
which,  contrary  to  human  and  divine  law,  sanction  usury 
and  compel  debtors  to  observe  usurious  contracts,  it  declares 
that  all  rulers  and  magistrates  knowingly  maintaining  such 
laws  are  to  incur  excommunication,  and  requires  the  legisla- 
tion in  question  to  be  revoked  within  three  months  Since 
the  true  nature  of  usurious  transactions  is  often  concealed 
beneath  various  specious  devices,  money-lenders  are  to  be 
compelled  by  the  ecclesiastical  authorities  to  submit  their 
accounts  to  examination.  Any  person  obstinately  declaring 
that  usury  is  not  a  sin  is  to  be  punished  as  a  heretic,  and  in- 
quisitors are  to  proceed  against  him  tanquam  contra  dif- 
jamatos  vcl  suspectos  de  haeresi.(yB 

It  would  not  be  easy  to  find  a  more  drastic  example, 
either  of  ecclesiastical  sovereignty,  or  of  the  attempt  to  assert 
the  superiority  of  the  moral  law  to  economic  expediency, 
than  the  requirement,  under  threat  of  excommunication,  that 
all  secular  legislation  sanctioning  usury  shall  be  repealed. 
But,  for  an  understanding  of  the  way  in  which  the  system 
was  intended  to  work,  the  enactments  of  Councils  are  per- 
haps less  illuminating  than  the  correspondence  between  the 
papal  Curia  and  subordinate  ecclesiastical  authorities  on 
specific  cases  and  questions  of  interpretation.  Are  the  heirs 


48  THE  MEDIEVAL  BACKGROUND 

of  those  who  have  made  money  by  usury  bound  to  make 
restitution?  Yes,  the  same  penalties  are  to  be  applied  to 
them  as  to  the  original  offenders.  The  pious  object  of  ran- 
soming prisoners  is  not  to  justify  the  asking  of  a  price  for 
a  loan  A  man  is  to  be  accounted  a  usurer,  not  only  if  he 
charges  interest,  but  if  he  allows  for  the  element  of  time  in 
a  bargain,  by  asking  a  higher  price  when  he  sells  on  credit 
Even  when  debtors  have  sworn  not  to  proceed  against 
usurers,  the  ecclesiastical  authorities  are  to  compel  the  lat 
ter  to  restore  their  gains,  and,  if  witnesses  are  terrorized  by 
the  protection  given  to  usurers  by  the  powerful,  punishment 
can  be  imposed  without  their  evidence,  provided  that  the 
offence  is  a  matter  of  common  notoriety  An  archbishop  of 
Canterbury  is  reminded  that  usury  is  perilous,  not  only  for 
the  clergy,  but  for  all  men  whatever,  and  is  warned  to  use 
ecclesiastical  censures  to  secure  the  restoration,  without  the 
deduction  of  interest,  of  property  which  has  been  pawned 
Usurers,  says  a  papal  letter  to  the  archbishop  of  Salerno, 
object  to  restoring  gains,  or  say  that  they  have  not  the 
means,  he  is  to  compel  all  who  can  to  make  restitution 
either  to  those  from  whom  interest  was  taken,  or  to  their 
heirs;  when  neither  course  is  possible,  they  are  to  give  it  to 
the  poor;  for,  as  Augustine  says,  non  rcmittitur  pcccatum, 
nisi  restituitur  ablatum  At  Genoa,  the  Pope  is  informed,  a 
practice  obtains  of  undertaking  to  pay,  at  the  end  of  a  given 
term,  a  higher  price  for  wares  than  they  were  worth  at  the 
moment  when  the  sale  took  place  It  is  not  clear  that  such 
contracts  are  necessarily  usurious,  nevertheless,  the  sellers 
run  into  sin,  unless  there  is  a  probability  that  the  wares  will 
have  changed  in  value  by  the  time  that  payment  is  made, 
"and  therefore  your  fellow-citizens  would  show  a  wise  re- 
gard for  their  salvation  if  they  ceased  making  contracts  of 
the  kind,  since  the  thoughts  of  men  cannot  be  concealed 
from  Almighty  God."  f><> 

It  is  evident  from  the  number  of  doubtful  cases  referred 
to  Rome  for  decision  that  the  law  with  regard  to  usury  was 
not  easily  administered  It  is  evident,  also,  that  efforts  were 
made  to  offer  guidance  in  dealing  with  difficult  and  technical 
problems.  In  the  book  of  common  forms,  drawn  up  in  the 
thirteenth  century  for  the  guidance  of  the  papal  penitentiary 
in  dealing  with  hard  cases,  precedents  were  inserted  to  show 
how  usurers  should  be  handled.70  About  the  same  time  ap- 
peared St.  Raymond's  guide  to  the  duties  of  an  archdeacon 


THE    SIN    OF  AVARICE  49 

which  contains  a  long  list  of  inquiries  to  be  made  on  visita- 
tion, covering  every  conceivable  kind  of  extortion,  and  de- 
signed to  expose  the  various  illusory  contracts — fictitious 
partnerships,  loans  under  the  guise  of  sales,  excessive  de- 
posits against  advances — by  which  the  offence  was  con- 
cealed.71 Instructions  to  confessors  define  in  equal  detail  the 
procedure  to  be  followed.  The  confessor,  states  a  series  of 
synodal  statutes,  is  to  "make  inquiry  concerning  merchan- 
dising, and  other  things  pertaining  to  avarice  and  covetous- 
ness  "  Barons  and  knights  are  to  be  requested  to  state 
whether  they  have  made  ordinances  contrary  to  the  liberty 
of  the  Church,  or  refused  justice  to  any  man  seeking  it,  or 
oppressed  their  subjects  with  undue  tallages,  tolls  or  services. 
"Concerning  burgesses,  merchants  and  officers  (ministrales) 
the  priest  is  to  make  inquiry  as  to  rapine,  usury,  pledges 
made  by  deceit  of  usury,  barratry,  false  and  lying  sales, 
unjust  weights  and  measures,  lying,  perjury  and  craft.  Con- 
cerning cultivators  (agncolas]  he  is  to  inquire  as  to  theft 
and  detention  of  the  property  of  others,  especially  with  re- 
gard to  tithes  .  .  also  as  to  the  removing  of  landmarks 
and  the  occupation  of  other  men's  land  .  .  .  Concerning 
avarice  it  is  to  be  asked  in  this  wise,  hast  thou  been  guilty 
of  simony  .  an  unjust  judge  ...  a  thief,  a  robber,  a 
perjurer,  a  sacrilegious  man,  a  gambler,  a  remover  of  land- 
marks in  fields  .  .  a  false  merchant,  an  oppressor  of  any 
man  and  above  all  of  widows,  wards  and  others  in  misery, 
for  the  sake  of  unjust  and  greedy  gain?"  Those  guilty  of 
avarice  are  to  do  penance  by  giving  large  alms,  on  the  prin- 
ciple that  "contraries  are  to  be  cured  with  contraries  "  But 
there  are  certain  sins  for  which  no  true  penitence  is  possible 
until  restitution  has  been  made  Of  these  usury  is  one;  and 
usury,  it  is  to  be  noted,  includes,  not  only  what  would  now 
be  called  interest,  but  the  sin  of  those  who,  on  account  of 
lapse  of  time,  sell  dearer  and  buy  cheaper.  If  for  practical 
reasons  restitution  is  impossible,  the  offender  is  to  be  in- 
structed to  require  that  it  shall  be  made  by  his  heirs,  and, 
when  the  injured  party  cannot  be  found,  the  money  is  to 
be  spent,  with  the  advice  of  the  bishop  if  the  sum  is  large 
and  of  the  priest  if  it  is  small,  "on  pious  works  and  espe- 
cially on  the  poor."  72 

The  more  popular  teaching  on  the  subject  is  illustrated 
by  the  manuals  for  use  in  the  confessional  and  by  books  for 
the  guidance  of  the  devout.  The  space  given  in  them  to  the 


50  THE  MEDIEVAL  BACKGROUND 

ethics  of  business  was  considerable.  In  the  fifteenth  century, 
Bishop  Pecock  could  meet  the  Lollards'  complaint  that  the 
Scriptures  were  buried  beneath  a  mass  of  interpretation,  by 
taking  as  his  illustration  the  books  which  had  been  written 
on  the  text,  "Lend,  hoping  for  nothing  again,"  and  arguing 
that  all  this  teaching  upon  usury  was  little  enough  "to  an- 
swer ...  all  the  hard,  scrupulous  doubts  and  questions 
which  all  day  have  need  to  be  assoiled  in  men's  bargains 
and  chaff erings  together."  73  A  century  later  there  were  re- 
gions in  which  such  doctrine  was  still  being  rehearsed  with 
all  the  old  rigor.  In  1552  the  Parliament  which  made  the 
Scottish  Reformation  was  only  eight  years  off.  But  the 
catechism  of  the  archbishop  of  St.  Andrews,  which  was  drawn 
up  in  that  year,  shows  no  disposition  to  compromise  with 
the  economic  frailties  of  his  fellow-countrymen.  It  denounces 
usurers,  masters  who  withhold  wages,  covetous  merchants 
who  sell  fraudulent  wares,  covetous  landlords  who  grind 
their  tenants,  and  in  general — a  comprehensive  and  embar- 
rassing indictment — "all  wretches  that  will  be  grown  rich 
incontinent,"  and  all  "who  may  keep  their  neighbor  from 
poverty  and  mischance  and  do  it  not."  74 

On  the  crucial  question,  how  the  ecclesiastical  courts  dealt 
in  practice  with  these  matters,  we  have  very  little  light 
They  are  still  almost  an  unworked  field.  On  the  Continent 
we  catch  glimpses  of  occasional  raids  Bishops  declare  war 
on  notorious  usurers,  only  to  evoke  reprisals  from  the  secular 
authorities,  to  whom  the  money-lender  is  too  convenient  to 
be  victimized  by  any  one  but  themselves. 7r>  At  the  end  of 
the  thirteenth  century  an  archbishop  of  Bourges  makes  some 
thirty-five  usurers  disgorge  at  a  sitting,70  and  seventy  years 
later  an  inquistor  at  Florence  collects  7,000  florins  in  two 
years  from  usurers  and  blasphemers.77  In  England  commer- 
cial morality  was  a  debatable  land,  in  which  ecclesiastical 
and  secular  authorities  contended  from  time  to  time  for 
jurisdiction.  The  ecclesiastical  courts  claimed  to  deal  with 
cases  of  breach  of  contract  in  general,  on  the  ground  that 
they  involved  laesio  fidei,  and  with  usury  in  particular,  as 
an  offence  against  morality  specifically  forbidden  by  the 
canon  law.  Both  claims  were  contested  by  the  Crown  and 
by  municipal  bodies.  The  former,  by  the  Constitutions  of 
Clarendon,78  had  expressly  reserved  proceedings  as  to  debts 
for  the  royal  courts,  and  the  same  rule  was  laid  down  more 
than  once  in  the  course  of  the  next  century.  The  latter  again 


THE    SIN    OF   AVARICE  51 

and  again  forbade  burgesses  to  take  proceedings  in  the  courts 
Christian,  and  fined  those  who  disregarded  the  prohibition,79 
Both,  in  spite  of  repeated  protests  from  the  clergy,80  made 
good  their  pretension  to  handle  usurious  contracts  in  secular 
courts,  but  neither  succeeded  in  ousting  the  jurisdiction  of 
the  Church  The  question  at  issue  was  not  whether  the 
usurer  should  be  punished — a  point  as  to  which  there  was 
only  one  opinion — but  who  should  have  the  lucrative  busi- 
ness of  punishing  him,  and  in  practice  he  ran  the  gauntlet 
of  all  and  of  each  Local  authorities,  from  the  City  of  London 
to  the  humblest  manorial  court,  make  by-laws  against  "un- 
lawful chevisance"  and  present  offenders  against  them.81 
The  Commons  pray  that  Lombard  brokers  may  be  banished, 
and  that  the  ordinances  of  London  concerning  them  may  be 
made  of  general  application  SJ  The  justices  in  eyre  hear  in- 
dictments of  usurers,8 '  and  the  Court  of  Chancery  handles 
petitions  from  victims  who  can  get  no  redress  at  common 
law  81  And  Holy  Church,  though  there  seems  to  be  only  one 
example  of  legislation  on  the  subject  by  an  English  Church 
Council/1  continues  to  deal  with  the  usurer  after  her  own 
manner 

For,  in  spite  of  the  conflict  of  jurisdictions,  the  rising  re- 
sentment against  the  ways  of  ecclesiastical  lawyers,  and  the 
expanding  capitalism  of  the  later  Middle  Ages,  it  is  evident 
that  commercial  cases  continued,  on  occasion  at  least,  to 
come  before  the  courts  Christian  Nor,  after  the  middle  of 
the  fourteenth  century,  was  their  right  to  try  cases  of  usury 
contested  by  the  secular  authorities  A  statute  of  1341  en- 
acted that  (as  laid  down  long  before)  the  King  should  have 
cognizance  of  usurers  dead,  and  the  Church  of  usurers  living. 
The  same  reservation  of  ecclesiastical  rights  was  repeated 
when  the  question  was  taken  up  a  century  later  under  Henry 
VII,  and  survived,  an  antiquated  piece  of  common  form, 
even  into  the  age  of  lusty  capitalism  under  Elizabeth  and 
James  I CG 

That  ecclesiastical  authorities  had  much  opportunity ^  of 
enforcing  the  canon  law  in  connection  with  money-lending 
is  improbable  It  was  naturally  in  the  commercial  towns 
that  cases  of  the  kind  most  frequently  arose,  and  the  towns 
did  not  look  with  favor  on  the  interference  of  churchmen  in 
matters  of  business.  In  London,  collisions  between  the  courts 
of  the  Official,  the  Mayor  and  the  King  were  frequent  in 
the  early  thirteenth  century.  Men  took  proceedings  before 


82  THE  MEDIEVAL  BACKGROUND 

the  first,  it  seems,  when  a  speedy  decision  was  desired,  or 
when  their  case  was  of  a  kind  which  secular  courts  were  not 
likely  to  regard  with  favor.  Thus  craftsmen,  to  give  one 
curious  example  out  of  many,  were  evidently  using  the 
courts  Christian  as  a  means  of  giving  effect  to  trade  union 
regulations,  which  were  more  likely  to  be  punished  than 
enforced  by  the  mayor  and  aldermen,  by  the  simple  device 
of  imposing  an  oath  and  proceeding  against  those  who  broke 
it  for  breach  of  faith.  The  smiths,  for  instance,  made  a 
"confederacy,"  supported  by  an  oath,  with  the  object,  as 
they  declared,  of  putting  down  night-work,  but,  as  was  al- 
leged in  court,  of  preventing  any  but  members  of  their 
organization  from  working  at  the  trade,  and  summoned 
blacklegs  before  the  ecclesiastical  courts.  The  spurriers  for- 
bade any  one  to  work  between  sunset  and  sunrise,  and  haled 
an  offending  journeyman  before  the  archdeacon,  with  the  re- 
sult that  "the  said  Richard,  after  being  three  times  warned 
by  the  Official,  had  been  expelled  from  the  Church  and 
excommunicated,  until  he  would  swear  to  keep  the  ordi- 
nance." 87 

Even  at  a  later  period  the  glimpses  which  we  catch  of  the 
activities  of  the  ecclesiastical  jurisdiction  are  enough  to  show 
that  it  was  not  wholly  a  dead  letter.  Priests  accused  of  usury 
undergo  correction  at  the  hands  of  their  bishops.88  Petition- 
ers appeal  for  redress  to  the  Court  of  Chancery  on  the 
ground  that  they  have  failed  to  secure  justice  in  the  courts 
of  bishops  or  archdeacons,  where  actions  on  cases  of  debts 
or  usury  have  been  begun  before  "spiritual  men."  89  The 
records  of  ecclesiastical  courts  show  that,  though  sometimes 
commercial  questions  were  dismissed  as  belonging  to  the 
secular  courts,  cases  of  breach  of  contract  and  usury  con- 
tinued, nevertheless,  to  be  settled  by  them.<)()  The  disrep- 
utable family  of  Marcroft — William  the  father  was  a  com- 
mon usurer,  Alice  his  daughter  baked  bread  at  Penteco$4 
and  Edward  his  son  made  a  shirt  on  All  Saints'  Day — is 
punished  by  the  ecclesiastical  court  of  Whalley  as  it  de- 
serves.91 At  Ripon  a  usurer  and  his  victim  are  induced  to 
settle  the  case  out  of  court €'2  The  Commissary  of  London 
cites  Thomas  Hall  super  crlmine  usurariae  pravitatis,  on  the 
ground  that,  having  advanced  four  shillings  on  the  security 
of  Thomas  Foster's  belt,  he  had  demanded  twelve  pence  over 
and  above  the  principal,  and  suspends  him  when  he  does 
not  appear  in  court.93  Nor  did  business  of  this  kind  cease 


THE    SIN    OF   AVARICE  S3 

with  the  Reformation  Cases  of  usury  were  being  heard  by 
ecclesiastical  courts  under  Elizabeth,  and  even  in  a  great 
commercial  center  like  the  City  of  London  it  was  still  pos- 
sible in  the  reign  of  James  I  for  the  Bishop's  Commissary 
to  be  trying  tradesmen  for  "lending  up  pawnes  for  an 
excessive  gain."  <)4 

It  was  not  only  by  legal  penalties,  however,  that  an  at- 
tempt was  made  to  raise  a  defensive  barrier  against  the 
exactions  of  the  money-lender  From  a  very  early  date  there 
was  a  school  of  opinion  which  held  that,  in  view  of  the 
various  stratagems  by  which  usurious  contracts  could  be 
"colored,"  direct  prohibition  was  almost  necessarily  impo- 
tent, and  which  favored  the  policy  of  providing  facilities 
for  borrowing  on  more  reasonable  terms  than  could  be  ob- 
tained from  the  money-lender  Ecclesiastics  try,  in  fact,  to 
turn  the  flank  of  the  usurer  by  establishing  institutions 
where  the  poor  can  raise  capital  cheaply.  Parishes,  religious 
fraternities,  gilds,  hospitals  and  perhaps  monasteries  lend 
corn,  cattle  and  money.')r>  In  England,  bishops  are  organizing 
such  loans  with  papal  approval  in  the  middle  of  the  thir- 
teenth century,96  and  two  centuries  later,  about  1462,  the 
Franciscans  lead  the  movement  for  the  creation  of  Monts 
dc  Ptctc,  which,  starting  in  Italy,  spread  by  the  first  half  of 
the  sixteenth  century  to  France,  Germany,  and  the  Low 
Countries,  and,  though  never  taken  up  in  England — for  the 
Reformation  intervened — supplied  a  topic  of  frequent  com- 
ment and  eulogy  to  English  writers  on  economic  ethics.97 
The  canon  law  on  the  subject  of  money-lending  underwent 
a  steady  development,  caused  by  the  necessity  of  adapting  it 
to  the  increasing  complexity  of  business  organization,  down 
at  least  to  the  Lateran  Council  of  1515  The  ingenuity  with 
which  professional  opinion  elaborated  the  code  was  itself  a 
proof  that  considerable  business — and  fees — were  the  result 
of  it,  for  lawyers  do  not  serve  God  for  naught  The  canon- 
ists, who  had  a  bad  reputation  with  the  laity,  were  not,  to 
put  it  mildly,  more  innocent  than  the  other  lawyers  in  the 
gentle  art  of  making  business  The  Italians,  in  particular, 
as  was  natural  in  the  financial  capital  of  Europe,  made  the 
pace,  and  Italian  canonists  performed  prodigies  of  legal  in- 
genuity. In  England,  on  the  other  hand,  either  because 
Englishmen  were  unusually  virtuous,  or,  as  a  foreigner  un- 
kindly said,  because  "they  do  not  fear  to  make  contracts  on 
usury/' 98  or,  most  probably,  because  English  business  was 


54  THE  MEDIEVAL  BACKGROUND 

a  conservative  and  slow-going  affair,  the  English  canonist 
Lyndwood  is  content  to  quote  a  sentence  from  an  English 
archbishop  of  the  thirteenth  century  and  to  leave  it  at  that." 
But,  however  lawyers  might  distinguish  and  refine,  the 
essential  facts  were  simple.  The  Church  sees  buying  and 
selling,  lending  and  borrowing,  as  a  simple  case  of  neighborly 
or  unneighborly  conduct.  Though  a  rationalist  like  Bishop 
Pecock  may  insist  that  the  rich,  as  such,  are  not  hateful  to 
God,100  it  has  a  traditional  prejudice  against  the  arts  by 
which  men — or  at  least  laymen — acquire  riches,  and  is  apt 
to  lump  them  together  under  the  ugly  name  of  avarice. 
Merchants  who  organize  a  ring,  or  money-lenders  who  grind 
the  poor,  it  regards,  not  as  business  strategists,  but  as 
nejandae  bdluae — monsters  of  iniquity.  As  for  grocers  and 
victualers  awho  conspire  wickedly  together  that  none  shall 
sell  better  cheap  than  another,"  and  speculators  uwho  buy 
up  corn,  meat  and  wine  ...  to  amass  money  at  the  cost 
of  others,"  they  are  "according  to  the  laws  of  the  Church 
no  better  than  common  criminals  "  1(n  So,  when  the  price  of 
bread  rises,  or  when  the  London  fruiterers,  persuaded  by  one 
bold  spirit  that  they  are  "all  poor  and  caitiffs  on  account 
of  their  own  simplicity,  and  if  they  would  act  on  his  advice 
they  would  be  rich  and  powerful,"  10J  form  a  combine,  to 
the  great  loss  and  hardship  of  the  people,  burgesses  and 
peasants  do  not  console  themselves  with  the  larger  hope  that 
the  laws  of  supply  and  demand  may  bring  prices  down  again 
Strong  in  the  approval  of  all  good  Christians,  they  stand  the 
miller  in  the  pillory,  and  reason  with  the  fruiterers  in  the 
court  of  the  mayor.  And  the  parish  priest  delivers  a  sermon 
on  the  sixth  commandment,  choosing  as  his  text  the  words 
of  the  Book  of  Proverbs,  "Give  me  neither  riches  nor  pov- 
erty, but  enough  for  my  sustenance." 

Ill     THE  IDEAL  AND  THE  REALITY 

Such,  in  brief  outline,  was  the  background  of  economic 
thought  which  the  sixteenth  century  inherited,  and  which 
it  brought  to  the  bewildering  changes  in  land  tenure,  in 
prices,  in  commercial  and  financial  organization,  that  made 
the  age  a  watershed  in  economic  development.  It  is  evident 
that  the  whole  implication  of  this  philosophy  was,  on  one 
side,  intensely  conservative.  There  was  no  question  of  prog- 
ress, still  less  of  any  radical  social  reconstruction.  In  the 


THE   IDEAL   AND    THE   REALITY  .5$ 

numerous  heretical  movements  of  the  Middle  Ages  social 
aspirations  were  often  combined  with  criticisms  of  the  luxury 
and  pomp  of  the  ecclesiastical  hierarchy.  The  official  Church, 
to  which  independence  of  thought  among  the  lower  orders 
was  but  little  less  abhorrent  when  it  related  to  their  tem- 
poral well-being  than  when  it  was  concerned  with  their 
eternal  salvation,  frowned  upon  these  dangerous  speculations, 
and  sometimes  crushed  them  with  a  ferocity  as  relentless  a* 
the  most  savage  of  the  White  Terrors  of  modern  history  has 
shown  to  the  most  formidable  of  insurrections 

Intellectually,  religious  opinion  endorsed  to  the  full  the 
static  view,  which  regarded  the  social  order  as  a  thing  un- 
alterable, to  be  accepted,  not  to  be  improved  Except  on  rare 
occasions,  its  spokesmen  repeated  the  conventional  doctrine, 
according  to  which  the  feet  were  born  to  labor,  the  hands  to 
fight,  and  the  head  to  rule.  Naturallv,  therefore,  they  de- 
nounced agitations,  like  the  communal  movement,103  de- 
signed to  overturn  that  natural  order,  though  the  rise  of 
the  Free  Cities  was  one  of  the  glories  of  medieval  Europe 
and  the  germ  of  almost  every  subsequent  advance  in  civil- 
ization They  referred  to  questions  of  economic  conduct,  not 
because  they  were  anxious  to  promote  reforms,  but  because 
they  were  concerned  with  the  maintenance  of  traditional 
standards  of  personal  morality,  of  which  economic  conduct 
formed  an  important  part. 

Practically,  the  Church  was  an  immense  vested  interest, 
implicated  to  the  hilt  in  the  economic  fabric,  especially  on 
the  side  of  agriculture  and  land  tenure.  Itself  the  greatest 
of  landowners,  it  could  no  more  quarrel  with  the  feudal 
structure  than  the  Ecclesiastical  Commission,  the  largest^  of 
mineral  owners  today,  can  lead  a  crusade  against  royalties. 
The  persecution  of  the  Spiritual  Franciscans,  who  dared,  in 
defiance  of  the  bull  of  John  XXII,  to  maintain  St.  Francis' 
rule  as  to  evangelical  poverty,  suggests  that  doctrines  im- 
pugning the  sanctity  of  wealth  resembled  too  closely  the 
teaching  of  Christ  to  be  acceptable  to  the  orinces  of  the 
Christian  Church. 

The  basis  of  the  whole  medieval  economic  system,  under 
which,  except  in  Italy  and  Flanders,  more  than  nine-tenths 
of  the  population  consisted  of  agriculturists,  had  been  serf- 
dom or  villeinage.  Confronted  in  the  sixteenth  century  with 
the  unfamiliar  evils  of  competitive  agriculture,  conservative 
reformers  were  to  sigh  for  the  social  harmonies  of  a  vanished 


56  THE  MEDIEVAL  BACKGROUND 

age,  which  "knyt  suche  a  knott  of  colaterall  amytie  betwene 
the  Lordes  and  the  tenaunts  that  the  Lorde  tendered  his 
tenaunt  as  his  childe,  and  the  tenaunts  againe  loved  and 
obeyed  the  Lorde  as  naturellye  as  the  childe  the  father."  1(H 
Their  idealization  of  the  past  is  as  misleading,  as  an  account 
of  the  conditions  of  previous  centuries,  as  it  is  illuminating 
as  a  comment  upon  those  of  their  own.  In  reality,  so  far  as 
the  servile  tenants,  who  formed  the  bulk  of  medieval  agri- 
culturists, were  concerned,  the  golden  age  of  peasant  pros- 
perity is,  except  here  and  there,  a  romantic  myth,  at  which 
no  one  would  have  been  more  surprised  than  the  peasants 
themselves.  The  very  essence  of  feudal  property  was  ex- 
ploitation in  its  most  naked  and  shameless  form,  compulsory 
labor,  additional  corvces  at  the  very  moments  when  the 
peasant's  labor  was  most  urgently  needed  on  his  own  hold- 
ing, innumerable  dues  and  payments,  the  obligation  to  grind 
at  the  lord's  mill  and  bake  at  the  lord's  oven,  the  private 
justice  of  the  lord's  court.  The  custom  of  the  manor,  the 
scarcity  of  labor,  and,  in  England,  the  steadily  advancing 
encroachments  of  the  royal  courts,  blunted  the  edge  of  the 
system,  and  in  fifteenth-century  England  a  prosperous  yeo- 
manry was  rising  on  its  ruins  But,  during  the  greater  part 
of  the  Middle  Ages,  its  cumulative  weight  had  been,  never- 
theless, immense  Those  who  lived  under  it  had  no  illusions 
as  to  its  harshness  The  first  step  which  the  peasant  who  had 
saved  a  little  money  took  was  to  buy  himself  out  of  the  obli- 
gations to  work  on  the  lord's  demesne.  The  Peasants'  Re- 
volt in  England,  the  Jacqucne  in  France  and  the  repeated 
risings  of  the  German  peasantry  reveal  a  state  of  social 
exasperation  which  has  been  surpassed  in  bitterness  by  few 
subsequent  movements. 

It  is  natural  to  ask  (though  some  writers  on  medieval  eco- 
nomics refrain  from  asking)  what  the  attitude  of  religious 
opinion  was  towards  serfdom.  And  it  is  hardly  possible  to  an- 
swer that  question  except  by  saying  that,  apart  from  a  few 
exceptional  individuals,  religious  opinion  ignored  it  True, 
the  Church  condemned  arbitrary  tallages,  and  urged  that  the 
serf  be  treated  with  humanity.  True,  it  described  the  manu- 
mission of  serfs  as  an  act  of  piety,  like  gifts  to  the  poor.  For 
serfs  are  not  "living  tools/'  but  men;  in  the  eyes  of  God  all 
men  are  serfs  together,  conservi,  and  in  the  Kingdom  of 
Heaven  Lazarus  is  before  Dives  lor>  True,  villeinage  was  a 
legal,  not  an  economic  category;  in  the  England  of  the  four- 


THE    IDEAL    AND    THE   REALITY  57 

teenth  century  there  were  serfs  who  were  rich  men.  But  to 
release  the  individual  is  not  to  condemn  the  institution. 
Whatever  "mad  priests"  might  say  and  do,  the  official 
Church,  whose  wealth  consisted  largely  of  villeins,  walked 
with  circumspection. 

The  canon  law  appears  to  have  recognized  and  enforced 
serfdom.100  Few  prominent  ecclesiastics  made  any  pronounce- 
ments against  it.  Aquinas  explains  it  as  the  result  of  sin,  but 
that  does  not  prevent  his  justifying  it  on  economic  grounds. IOT 
Almost  all  medieval  writers  appear  to  assume  it  or  excuse  it. 
Ecclesiastical  landlords,  though  perhaps  somewhat  more  con- 
servative in  their  methods,  seem  as  a  whole  to  have  been 
neither  better  nor  worse  than  other  landlords.  Rustica  gens 
optima  flens,  pessima  gaud  ens,  was  a  sentiment  which  some- 
times appealed,  it  is  to  be  feared,  to  the  children  of  light 
concerned  with  rent  rolls  and  farming  profits,  not  less  than 
to  the  feudal  aristocracy,  with  whom  the  heads  of  the  ecclesi- 
astical hierarchy  were  inextricably  intermingled.  When  their 
chance  came,  John  Nameless,  and  John  the  Miller,  and  John 
Carter,  who  may  be  presumed  to  have  known  their  friends, 
burned  the  court  rolls  of  an  abbot  of  St  Albans,  and  cut  off 
the  head  of  an  archbishop,  and  ran  riot  on  the  estates  of  an 
abbot  of  Kempten,  with  not  less  enthusiasm  than  they 
showed  in  plundering  their  lay  exploiters.  It  was  not  the 
Church,  but  revolting  peasants  in  Germany  and  England, 
who  appealed  to  the  fact  that  "Christ  has  made  all  men 
free",los  and  in  Germany,  at  least,  their  ecclesiastical  masters 
showed  small  mercy  to  them.  The  disappearance  of  serfdom 
— and,  after  all,  it  did  not  disappear  from  France  till  late  in 
the  eighteenth  century,  and  from  Germany  till  the  nineteenth 
— was  part  of  a  general  economic  movement,  with  which  the 
Church  had  little  to  do,  and  which  churchmen,  as  property- 
owners,  had  sometimes  resisted.  It  owed  less  to  Christianity 
than  to  the  humanitarian  liberalism  of  the  French  Revo- 
lution. 

The  truth  was  that  the  very  triumph  of  the  Church  closed 
its  mouth.  The  Church  of  the  third  century,  a  minority  of 
believers  confronted  with  an  alien  civilization,  might  protest 
and  criticize.  But,  when  the  whole  leaven  was  mixed  with  the 
lump,  when  the  Church  was  regarded,  not  as  a  society,  but  as 
society  itself,  it  was  inevitably  diluted  by  the  mass  which  it 
absorbed.  The  result  was  a  compromise — a  compromise  of 


58  THE    MEDIEVAL    BACKGROUND 

which  the  critic  can  say,  "How  much  that  was  intolerable 
was  accepted! "  and  the  eulogist,  "How  much  that  was  intol- 
erable was  softened!" 

Both  critic  and  eulogist  are  right.  For  if  religious  opinion 
acquiesced  in  much,  it  also  claimed  much,  and  the  habit  of 
mind  which  made  the  medieval  Church  almost  impotent  when 
dealing  with  the  serried  abuses  of  the  medieval  land  system 
was  precisely  that  which  made  it  strong,  at  least  in  theory,  in 
dealing  with  the  economic  transactions  of  the  individual.  In 
the  earlier  Middle  Ages  it  had  stood  for  the  protection  of 
peaceful  labor,  for  the  care  of  the  poor,  the  unfortunate  and 
the  oppressed — for  the  ideal,  at  least,  of  social  solidarity 
against  the  naked  force  of  violence  and  oppression.  With  the 
growing  complexity  of  economic  civilization,  it  was  confront- 
ed with  problems  not  easily  handled  by  its  traditional  cate- 
gories. But,  if  applied  capriciously,  they  were  not  renounced, 
and  the  world  of  economic  morality,  which  baffles  us  today, 
was  in  its  turn  converted  by  it  into  a  new,  though  embar- 
rassing, opportunity.  Whatever  emphasis  may  be  laid — and 
emphasis  can  hardly  be  too  strong — upon  the  gulf  between 
theory  and  practice,  the  qualifications  stultifying  principles, 
and  the  casuistry  by  which  the  work  of  canonists,  not  less 
than  of  other  lawyers,  was  disfigured,  the  endeavor  to  draw 
the  most  commonplace  of  human  activities  and  the  least  trac- 
table of  human  appetites  within  the  all-embracing  circle  of 
a  universal  system  still  glows  through  it  all  with  a  certain 
tarnished  splendor.  When  the  distinction  between  that  which 
is  permissible  in  private  life  and  that  which  is  permissible 
in  business  offers  so  plausible  an  escape  from  the  judgment 
pronounced  on  covetousness,  it  is  something  to  have  insisted 
that  the  law  of  charity  is  binding  on  the  second  not  less 
than  on  the  first  WThen  the  austerity  of  principles  can  be 
evaded  by  treating  them  as  applicable  only  to  those  relations 
of  life  in  which  their  application  is  least  exacting,  it  is  some- 
thing to  have  attempted  to  construct  a  system  tough  enough 
to  stand  against  commercial  unscrupulousness,  but  yet  suffi- 
ciently elastic  to  admit  any  legitimate  transaction.  If  it  is 
proper  to  insist  on  the  prevalence  of  avarice  and  greed  in  high 
places,  it  is  not  less  important  to  observe  that  men  called 
these  vices  by  their  right  names,  and  had  not  learned  to  per- 
suade themselves  that  greed  was  enterprise  and  avarice 
economy. 

Such  antitheses  are  tempting,  and  it  is  not  surprising  that 


THE   IDEAL   AND   THE   REALITY  59 

some  writers  should  have  dwelt  upon  them.  To  a  generation 
disillusioned  with  free  competition,  and  disposed  to  demand 
some  criterion  of  social  expediency  more  cogent  than  the  ver- 
dict of  the  market,  the  jealous  and  cynical  suspicion  of  eco- 
nomic egotism,  which  was  the  prevalent  mood  of  the  Middle 
Ages,  is  more  intelligible  than  it  was  to  the  sanguine  opti- 
mists of  the  Age  of  Reason,  which,  as  far  as  its  theory  of  the 
conduct  of  men  in  society  is  concerned,  deserves  much  more 
than  the  thirteenth  century  to  be  described  as  the  Age  of 
Faith.  In  the  twentieth  century,  with  its  trusts  and  combines, 
its  control  of  industry  by  business  and  of  both  by  finance,  its 
attempts  to  fix  fair  wages  and  fair  prices,  its  rationing  and 
food  controls  and  textile  controls,  the  economic  harmonies 
are,  perhaps,  a  little  blown  upon.  The  temper  in  which  it  ap- 
proaches questions  of  economic  organization  appears  to  have 
more  affinity  with  the  rage  of  the  medieval  burgess  at  the 
uncharitable  covetousness  of  the  usurer  and  the  engrosser, 
than  it  has  with  the  confidence  reposed  by  its  innocent  grand- 
fathers in  the  infallible  operations  of  the  invisible  hand. 

The  resemblance,  however,  though  genuine,  is  superficial, 
and  to  overemphasize  it  is  to  do  less  than  justice  to  precisely 
those  elements  in  medieval  thought  which  were  most  charac- 
teristic. The  significance  of  its  contribution  consists,  not  in 
its  particular  theories  as  to  prices  and  interest,  which  recur 
in  all  ages,  whenever  the  circumstances  of  the  economic  en- 
vironment expose  consumer  and  borrower  to  extortion,  but  in 
its  insistence  that  society  is  a  spiritual  organism,  not  an  eco- 
nomic machine,  and  that  economic  activity,  which  is  one  sub- 
ordinate element  within  a  vast  and  complex  unity,  requires 
to  be  controlled  and  repressed  by  reference  to  the  moral  ends 
for  which  it  supplies  the  material  means.  So  merciless  is  the 
tyranny  of  economic  appetites,  so  prone  to  self-aggrandize- 
ment the  empire  of  economic  interests,  that  a  doctrine  which 
confines  them  to  their  proper  sphere,  as  the  servant,  not  the 
master,  of  civilization,  may  reasonably  be  regarded  as  among 
the  pregnant  truisms  which  are  a  permanent  element  in  any 
sane  philosophy.  Nor  it  it,  perhaps,  as  clear  today  as  it 
seemed  a  century  ago,  that  it  has  been  an  unmixed  gain  to 
substitute  the  criterion  of  economic  expediency,  so  easily  in- 
terpreted in  terms  of  quantity  and  mass,  for  the  conception 
of  a  rule  of  life  superior  to  individual  desires  and  temporary 
exigencies,  which  was  what  the  medieval  theorist  meant  by 
"natural  law." 


60  THE    MEDIEVAL   BACKGROUND 

When  all  is  said,  the  fact  remains  that,  on  the  small  scale 
involved,  the  problem  of  moralizing  economic  life  was  faced 
and  not  abandoned.  The  experiment  may  have  been  imprac- 
ticable, and  almost  from  the  first  it  was  discredited  by  the 
notorious  corruption  of  ecclesiastical  authorities,  who 
preached  renunciation  and  gave  a  lesson  in  greed.  But  it  had 
in  it  something  of  the  heroic,  and  to  ignore  the  nobility  of  the 
conception  is  not  less  absurd  than  to  idealize  its  practical  re- 
sults. The  best  proof  of  the  appeal  which  the  attempt  to  sub- 
ordinate economic  interests  to  religion  had  made  is  the  per- 
sistence of  the  same  attempt  among  reformers,  to  whom  the 
Pope  was  anti-Christ  and  the  canon  law  an  abomination  and 
the  horror  of  decent  men  when,  in  the  sixteenth  century,  its 
breakdown  became  too  obvious  to  be  contested. 


CHAPTER  II 

The   Continental  Reformers 

"Neither  the  Church  of  Christ,  nor  a  Christian  Commonwealth, 
ought  to  tolerate  such  as  prefer  private  gam  to  the  public  weal,  or 
seek  it  to  the  hurt  of  their  neighbours  " 

BuctR,  De  Rcgno  Christi. 

LORD  ACTON,  in  an  unforgettable  passage  in  his  Inaugural 
Lecture  on  the  Study  of  History,  has  said  that  "after  many 
ages  persuaded  of  the  headlong  decline  and  impending  disso- 
lution of  society,  and  governed  by  usage  and  the  will  of  mas- 
ters who  were  in  their  graves,  the  sixteenth  century  went 
forth  armed  for  untried  experience,  and  ready  to  watch  with 
hopefulness  a  prospect  of  incalculable  change."  1  His  refer- 
ence was  to  the  new  world  revealed  by  learning,  by  science, 
and  by  discovery  But  his  words  offer  an  appropriate  text 
for  a  discussion  of  the  change  in  the  conception  of  the  rela- 
tions between  religion  and  secular  interests  which  took  place 
in  the  same  period.  Its  inevitable  consequence  was  the  emer- 
gence, after  a  prolonged  moral  and  intellectual  conflict,  of 
new  conceptions  of  social  expediency  and  of  new  lines  of 
economic  thought. 

The  strands  in  this  movement  were  complex,  and  the  for- 
mula which  associates  the  Reformation  with  the  rise  of  eco- 
nomic individualism  is  no  complete  explanation  Systems  pre- 
pare their  own  overthrow  by  a  preliminary  process  of  petri- 
faction The  traditional  social  philosophy  was  static,  in  the 
sense  that  it  assumed  a  body  of  class  relations  sharply  de- 
fined by  custom  and  law,  and  little  affected  by  the  ebb  and 
flow  of  economic  movements  Its  weakness  in  the  face  of 
novel  forces  was  as  obvious  as  the  strain  put  upon  it  by  the 
revolt  against  the  source  of  ecclesiastical  jurisprudence,  the 
partial  discredit  of  the  canon  law  and  of  ecclesiastical  disci- 
pline, and  the  rise  of  a  political  science  equipped  from  the 
arsenals  of  antiquity  But  it  is  not  to  under-estimate  the  ef- 
fect of  the  Reformation  to  say  that  the  principal  causes  mak- 
ing the  age  a  watershed,  from  which  new  streams  of  social 
theory  descend,  lay  in  another  region  Mankind  does  not  re- 
flect upon  questions  of  economic  and  social  organization  un- 
til compelled  to  do  so  by  the  sharp  pressure  of  some  practical 

61 


62  THE   CONTINENTAL   REFORMERS 

emergency.  The  sixteenth  century  was  an  age  of  social  spec- 
ulation for  the  same  reason  as  the  early  nineteenth — because 
it  was  an  age  of  social  dislocation.  The  retort  of  conservative 
religious  teachers  to  a  spirit  which  seems  to  them  the  triumph 
of  Mammon  produces  the  last  great  literary  expression  of  the 
appeal  to  the  average  conscience  which  had  been  made  by  an 
older  social  order.  The  practical  implications  of  the  social 
theory  of  the  Middle  Ages  are  stated  more  clearly  in  the  six- 
teenth century  than  even  in  its  zenith,  because  they  are  stated 
with  the  emphasis  of  a  creed  which  is  menaced. 

I.    THE    ECONOMIC    REVOLUTION 

The  religious  revolution  of  the  age  came  on  a  world  heav- 
ing with  the  vastest  economic  crisis  that  Europe  had  experi- 
enced since  the  fall  of  Rome.  Art  and  scientific  curiosity 
and  technical  skill,  learning  and  statesmanship,  the  scholar- 
ship which  explored  the  past  and  the  prophetic  vision  which 
pierced  the  future,  had  all  poured  their  treasures  into  the 
sumptuous  shrine  of  the  new  civilization.  Behind  the  genii  of 
beauty  and  wisdom  who  were  its  architects  there  moved  a 
murky,  but  indispensable,  figure.  It  was  the  demon  whom 
Dante  had  met  muttering  gibberish  in  the  fourth  circle  of  the 
Inferno,  and  whom  Sir  Guyon  was  to  encounter  three  cen- 
turies later,  tanned  with  smoke  and  seared  with  fire,  in  a  cave 
adjoining  the  mouth  of  hell  His  uncouth  labors  quarried  the 
stones  which  Michael  Angelo  was  to  raise,  and  sank  deep  in 
the  Roman  clay  the  foundations  of  the  walls  to  be  adorned 
by  Raphael. 

For  it  was  the  mastery  of  man  over  his  environment  which 
heralded  the  dawn  of  the  new  age,  and  it  was  in  the  stress 
of  expanding  economic  energies  that  this  mastery  was  proved 
and  won.  Like  sovereignty  in  a  feudal  society,  the  economic 
efforts  of  the  Middle  Ages,  except  in  a  few  favored  spots,  had 
been  fragmentary  and  decentralized.  Now  the  scattered  raid- 
ers were  to  be  organized  and  disciplined;  the  dispersed  and 
irregular  skirmishes  were  to  be  merged  in  a  grand  struggle, 
on  a  front  which  stretched  from  the  Baltic  to  the  Ganges  and 
from  the  Spice  Islands  to  Peru.  Every  year  brought  the  news 
of  fresh  triumphs.  The  general  who  marshaled  the  host  and 
launched  the  attack  was  economic  power. 

Economic  power,  long  at  home  in  Italy,  was  leaking 
through  a  thousand  creeks  and  inlets  into  western  Europe,  for 


THE   ECONOMIC   REVOLUTION  63 

a  century  before,  with  the  climax  of  the  great  Discoveries, 
the  flood  came  on  breast-high  Whatever  its  truth  as  a  judg- 
ment on  the  politics  of  the  fifteenth  century,  the  conventional 
verdict  on  its  futility  does  scanty  justice  to  its  economic  sig- 
nificance It  was  in  an  age  of  political  anarchy  that  the  forces 
destined  to  dominate  the  future  tried  their  wings.  The  era  of 
Columbus  and  Da  Gama  was  prepared  by  the  patient  labor 
of  Italian  cartographers  and  Portuguese  seamen,  as  certainly 
as  was  that  of  Crompton  and  Watt  by  the  obscure  experi- 
ments of  nameless  predecessors. 

The  master  who  set  the  problem  that  the  heroes  of  the  age 
were  to  solve  was  material  necessity  The  Europe  of  the  ear- 
liei  Middle  Ages,  like  the  world  of  the  twentieth  century,  had 
been  a  closed  circle  But  it  had  been  closed,  not  by  the 
growth  of  knowledge,  but  by  the  continuance  of  ignorance; 
and,  while  the  latter,  having  drawn  the  whole  globe  into  a 
single  economic  system,  has  no  space  left  for  fresh  expan- 
sion, for  the  former,  with  the  Mediterranean  as  its  immemo- 
rial pivot,  expansion  had  hardly  begun  Tapping  the  wealth 
of  the  EaM:  by  way  of  the  narrow  apertures  in  the  Levant,  it 
resembled,  in  the  rigidity  of  the  limits  imposed  on  its  com- 
mercial strategy,  a  giant  fed  through  the  chinks  of  a  wall. 

As  was  the  general  scheme,  so  were  the  details,  inelastic  in 
its  external  Europe  was  hardly  more  flexible  in  its  internal, 
relations  Its  primary  unit  had  been  the  village;  and  the  vil- 
lage, a  community  of  agrarian  shareholders  fortified  by  cus- 
tom, had  repressed  with  a  fury  of  virtuous  unanimity  the  dis- 
orderly appetites  whi(  h  menaced  its  traditional  routine  with 
the  evil  whose  name  is  Change  Beyond  the  village  lay  the 
greater,  more  privileged,  village  called  the  borough,  and  the 
brethren  of  borough  and  gild  had  turned  on  the  foreign  devil 
from  upland  and  valley  a  face  of  flint  Above  both  were  the 
slowly  waking  nations  Nationalism  was  an  economic  force 
before  nationality  was  a  political  fact,  and  it  was  a  sound 
reason  for  harrying  a  competitor  that  he  was  a  Florentine  or 
a  man  of  the  E'mperor  The  privileged  colonv  with  its  depot, 
the  Steel-yard  of  the  Hanseatic  League,  the  Fondaco  Tedesco 
of  the  south  Germans,  the  Factory  of  the  English  Merchant 
Adventurers,  were  but  tiny  breaches  in  a  wall  of  economic 
exclusiveness  Trade,  as  in  modern  Turkey  or  China,  was 
carried  on  under  capitulations. 

This  narrow  framework  had  been  a  home.  In  the  fifteenth 
century  it  was  felt  to  be  a  prison.  Expanding  energies  pressed 


64  THE    CONTINENTAL   REFORMERS 

against  the  walls;  restless  appetites  gnawed  and  fretted 
wherever  a  crack  in  the  surface  offered  room  for  erosion. 
Long  before  the  southward  march  of  the  Turks  cut  the  last 
of  the  great  routes  from  the  East,  the  Venetian  monopoly  was 
felt  to  be  intolerable.  Long  before  the  plunder  of  Mexico  and 
the  silver  of  Potosi  flooded  Europe  with  treasure,  the  mines 
of  Germany  and  the  Tyrol  were  yielding  increasing,  if  still 
slender,  streams  of  bullion,  which  stimulated  rather  than  al- 
]a}'ed  its  thirst.2  It  was  not  the  lords  of  great  estates,  but 
eager  and  prosperous  peasants,  who  in  England  first  nibbled 
at  commons  and  undermined  the  manorial  custom,  behind 
which,  as  behind  a  dyke,  their  small  savings  had  been  accu- 
mulated. It  was  not  great  capitalists,  but  enterprising  gilds- 
men,  who  began  to  make  the  control  of  the  fraternity  the 
basis  of  a  system  of  plutocratic  exploitation,  or  who  fled,  pre- 
cocious individualists,  from  the  fellowship  of  borough  and 
craft,  that  they  might  grow  to  what  stature  they  pleased  in 
rural  isolation.  It  was  not  even  the  Discoveries  which  first 
began  the  enormous  tilt  of  economic  power  from  south  and 
east  to  north  and  west  The  records  of  German  and  English 
trade  suggest  that  the  powers  of  northern  Europe  had  for  a 
century  before  the  Discoveries  been  growing  in  wealth  and 
civilization, s  and  for  a  century  after  them  English  economic 
development  was  to  be  as  closely  wedded  to  its  continental 
connections  as  though  Diaz  had  never  rounded  the  Cape,  nor 
Columbus  praised  Heaven  for  leading  him  to  the  shores  of 
Zayton  and  Guinsay  First  attempted  as  a  counterpoise  to  the 
Italian  monopolist,  then  pressed  home  with  ever  greater  ea- 
gerness to  turn  the  flank  of  the  Turk,  as  his  strangle-hold  on 
the  eastern  commerce  tightened,  the  Discoveries  were  neither 
a  happy  accident  nor  the  fruit  of  the  disinterested  curiosity 
of  science.  They  were  the  climax  of  almost  a  century  of  pa- 
tient economic  effort.  They  were  as  practical  in  their  motive 
as  the  steam-engine. 

The  result  was  not  the  less  sensational  because  it  had  been 
long  prepared.  Heralded  by  an  economic  revolution  not  less 
profound  than  that  of  three  centuries  later,  the  new  world 
of  the  sixteenth  century  took  its  character  from  the  outburst 
of  economic  energy  in  which  it  had  been  born.  Like  the  nine- 
teenth century,  it  saw  a  swift  increase  in  wealth  and  an  im- 
pressive expansion  of  trade,  a  concentration  of  financial  pow- 
er on  a  scale  unknown  before,  the  rise,  amid  fierce  social  con- 
vulsions, of  new  classes  and  the  depression  of  old,  the  tri- 


THE    ECONOMIC    REVOLUTION  65 

umph  of  a  new  culture  and  system  of  ideas  amid  struggles 
not  less  bitter. 

It  was  an  age  of  economic,  not  less  than  of  political,  sensa- 
tions, which  were  recorded  in  the  letter-books4  of  business 
men  as  well  as  in  the  state  papers  of  Governments.  The  de- 
cline of  Venice  and  of  the  south  German  cities  which  had 
distributed  the  products  that  Venice  imported,  and  which 
henceforward  must  either  be  marooned  far  from  the  new 
trade  routes  or  break  out  to  the  sea,  as  some  of  them  did,  by 
way  of  the  Low  Countries;  the  new  economic  imperialism  of 
Portugal  and  Spain,  the  outburst  of  capitalist  enterprise  in 
mining  and  textiles,  the  rise  of  commercial  companies,  no 
longer  local  but  international,  and  based,  not  merely  on  ex- 
clusive privileges,  but  on  the  power  of  massed  capital  to  drive 
from  the  field  all  feebler  competitors;  a  revolution  in  prices 
which  shattered  all  customary  relationships,  the  collapse  of 
medieval  rural  society  in  a  nightmare  of  peasants'  wars;  the 
subjection  of  the  collegiate  industrial  organization  of  the 
Middle  Ages  to  a  new  money-power,  the  triumph  of  the 
State  and  its  conquest,  in  great  parts  of  Europe,  of  the 
Church — all  were  crowded  into  less  than  two  generations.  A 
man  who  was  born  when  the  Council  of  Basel  was  sitting 
saw  also,  if  he  lived  to  a  ripe  old  age,  the  dissolution  of  the 
English  monasteries  At  the  first  date  Portuguese  explorers 
had  hardly  passed  Sierra  Leone;  at  the  second  Portugal  had 
been  the  master  of  an  Indian  Empire  for  almost  a  generation. 
In  the  intervening  three-quarters  of  a  century  the  whole 
framework  of  European  civilization  had  been  transformed. 

Compared  with  the  currents  which  raced  in  Italy,  or  Ger- 
many, or  the  Low  Countries,  English  life  was  an  economic 
back-water.  But  even  its  stagnant  shallows  were  stirred  by 
the  eddy  and  rush  of  the  continental  whirlpool.  When  Henry 
VII  came  to  the  throne,  the  economic  organization  of  the 
country  differed  but  little  from  that  of  the  age  of  Wyclif. 
When  Henry  VIII  died,  full  of  years  and  sin,  some  of  the 
main  characteristics  which  were  to  distinguish  it  till  the  ad- 
vent of  steam-power  and  machinery  could  already,  though 
faintly,  be  descried.  The  door  that  remained  to  be  unlocked 
was  colonial  expansion,  and  forty  years  later  the  first  experi- 
ments in  colonial  expansion  had  begun. 

The  phenomenon  which  dazzled  contemporaries  was  the 
swift  start  into  apparent  opulence,  first  of  Portugal  and  then 


66  THE    CONTINENTAL   REFORMERS 

of  Spain.  The  nemesis  of  parasitic  wealth  was  not  discerned, 
and  it  was  left  for  the  cynical  rationalism  of  an  ambassador 
of  that  commercial  republic,  in  comparison  with  whose  hoary 
wisdom  the  new  plutocrats  of  the  West  were  meddlesome 
children,  to  observe  that  the  true  mines  of  the  Spanish  Em- 
pire lay,  not  in  America,  but  in  the  sodden  clay  of  the  water- 
logged Netherlands  5  The  justice  of  the  criticism  was  revealed 
when  Spain,  a  corpse  bound  on  the  back  of  the  most  liberal 
and  progressive  community  of  the  age,  completed  her  own 
ruin  by  sacking  the  treasury  from  which,  far  more  than  from 
Potosi,  her  wealth  had  been  drawn.  But  the  beginnings  of 
that  long  agony,  in  which  the  powerhouse  of  European  ente'- 
prise  was  to  be  struck  with  paralysis,  still  lay  in  the  future, 
and  later  generations  of  Spaniards  looked  back  with  pardon- 
able exaggeration  on  the  closing  years  of  Charles  V  as  a 
golden  age  of  economic  prosperity  Europe  as  a  whole,  how- 
ever lacerated  by  political  and  religious  struggles,  seemed  to 
have  solved  the  most  pressing  economic  problems  which  had 
haunted  her  in  the  later  Middle  Ages.  During  a  thousand 
years  of  unresting  struggle  with  marsh  and  forest  and  moor 
she  had  colonized  her  own  waste  places  That  tremendous 
achievement  almost  accomplished,  she  now  turned  to  the 
task  of  colonizing  the  world  No  longer  on  the  defensive,  she 
entered  on  a  phase  of  economic  expansion  which  was  to  grow 
for  the  next  four  hundred  years,  and  which  only  in  the  twen- 
tieth century  was  to  show  signs  of  drawing  towards  its  close 
Once  a  year  she  was  irrigated  with  the  bullion  of  America, 
once  a  year  she  was  enriched  with  a  golden  harvest  from  tho 
East.  The  period  of  mere  experiment  over,  and  the  new  con- 
nections firmly  established,  she  appeared  to  be  in  sight  of  an 
economic  stability  based  on  broader  foundations  than  ever 
before. 

Portugal  and  Spain  held  the  keys  of  the  treasure-house  of 
East  and  West  But  it  was  not  Portugal,  with  her  tiny  pop- 
ulation, and  her  empite  that  was  little  more  than  a  line  of 
forts  and  factories  10,000  miles  long,  nor  Spain,  for  centuries 
an  army  on  the  march,  and  now  staggering  beneath  the  re- 
sponsibilities of  her  vast  and  scattered  empire,  devout  to  fa- 
naticism, and  with  an  incapacity  for  economic  affairs  which 
seemed  almost  inspired,  who  reaped  the  material  harvest  of 
the  empires  into  which  they  had  stepped,  the  one  by  patient 
toil,  the  other  by  luck.  Gathering  spoils  which  they  could  not 
retain,  and  amassing  wealth  which  slipped  through  their  fin- 


THE   ECONOMIC   REVOLUTION  6? 

gers,  they  were  little  more  than  the  political  agents  of  minds 
more  astute  and  characters  better  versed  in  the  arts  of  peace. 
Every  period  and  society  has  some  particular  center,  or  in- 
stitution, or  social  class,  in  which  the  characteristic  qualities 
of  its  genius  seem  to  be  fixed  and  embodied.  In  the  Europe  of 
the  early  Renaissance  the  heart  of  the  movement  had  been 
Italy.  In  the  Europe  of  the  Reformation  it  was  the  Low  Coun 
tries.  The  economic  capital  of  the  new  civilization  was  Ant- 
werp The  institution  which  best  symbolized  its  eager  ener- 
gies was  the  international  money-market  and  produce-ex- 
change. Its  typical  figure,  the  paymaster  of  princes,  was  the 
international  financier. 

Before  it  was  poisoned  by  persecution,  revolution  and  war, 
the  spirit  of  the  Netherlands  found  its  purest  incarnation  in 
Erasmus,  a  prophet  without  sackcloth  and  a  reformer  un- 
touched by  heat  or  fury,  to  the  universal  internationalism  of 
whose  crystal  spirit  the  boundaries  of  States  were  a  pattern 
scrawled  to  amuse  the  childish  malice  of  princes  Of  that  cos- 
mopolitan country,  destined  to  be  the  refuge  of  the  interna- 
tional idea  when  outlawed  by  every  other  power  in  Europe 
Antwerp,  "a  home  common  to  all  nations/'  was  the  most 
cosmopolitan  city.  Made  famous  as  a  center  of  learning  by 
Plantings  press,  the  metropolis  of  painting  in  a  country  where 
painting  was  almost  a  national  industry,  it  was  at  once  the 
shrine  to  which  masters  like  Cranach,  Durer  and  Holbein 
made  their  pilgrimage  of  devotion,  and  an  asylum  which 
offered  to  the  refugees  of  less  happy  countries  a  haven  as  yet 
undisturbed  by  any  sy^ematic  campaign  to  stamp  out  heresy. 
In  the  exuberance  of  its  intellectual  life,  as  in  the  glitter  of 
its  material  prosperity,  the  thinker  and  the  reformer  found 
a  spiritual  home,  where  the  energies  of  the  new  age  seemed 
gathered  for  a  bound  into  that  land  of  happiness  and 
dreams,  for  the  scene  of  which  More,  who  knew  his  Europe 
chose  as  the  le*st  incredible  setting  the  garden  of  his  lodg 
ings  at  Antwerp. 

The  economic  preeminence  of  Antwerp  owed  much  to  the 
industrial  region  behind  it,  from  which  the  woollen  and  wor- 
steds of  Valenciennes  and  Tournai,  the  tapestries  of  Brussels 
and  Oudenarde,  the  iron  of  Namur,  annd  the  munitions^  of 
the  Black  Country  round  Liege,  poured  in  an  unceasing 
stream  on  to  its  quays  6  But  Antwerp  was  a  European,  rather 
than  a  Flemish,  metropolis.  Long  the  competitor  of  Bruges 
for  the  reception  of  the  two  great  currents  of  trade  from  the 


68  THE    CONTINENTAL    REFORMERS 

Mediterranean  and  the  Baltic,  which  met  in  the  Low  Coun- 
tries, by  the  last  quarter  of  the  fifteenth  century  she  had 
crushed  her  rival.  The  Hanse  League  maintained  a  depot  at 
Antwerp;  Italian  banking  firms  in  increasing  numbers  opened 
businesses  there;  the  English  Merchant  Adventurers  made  it 
the  entrepot  through  which  English  cloth,  long  its  principal 
import,  was  distributed  to  northern  Europe,  the  copper  mar- 
ket moved  from  Venice  to  Antwerp  in  the  nineties  Then 
came  the  great  Discoveries,  and  Antwerp,  the  first  city  to  tap 
the  wealth,  not  of  an  inland  sea,  but  of  the  ocean,  stepped 
into  a  position  of  unchallenged  preeminence  almost  unique 
in  European  history.  The  long  sea-roads  which  ran  east  and 
west  met  and  ended  in  its  harbors.  The  Portuguese  Govern- 
ment made  it  in  1503  the  depot  of  the  Eastern  spice  trade 
From  the  accession  of  Charles  V  it  was  the  commercial  cap- 
ital of  the  Spanish  Empire,  and,  in  spite  of  protests  that  the 
precious  metals  were  leaving  Spain,  the  market  for  American 
silver.  Commerce,  with  its  demand  for  cheap  and  easy  cred- 
it, brought  finance  in  its  train.  The  commercial  companies 
and  banking  houses  of  south  Germany  turned  from  the  dwin- 
dling trade  across  the  Alps,  to  make  Antwerp  the  base  for 
financial  operations  of  unexampled  magnitude  and  com- 
plexity.7 

In  such  an  economic  forcing-house  new  philosophies  of  so- 
ciety, like  new  religious  creeds,  found  a  congenial  soil  Pro- 
fessor Pirenne  has  contrasted  the  outlook  for  the  medieval 
middle  class,  intent  on  the  conservation  of  corporate  and  lo- 
cal privileges,  with  that  of  the  new  plutocracy  of  the  six- 
teenth century,  with  its  international  ramifications,  its  inde- 
pendence of  merely  local  interests,  its  triumphant  vindication 
of  the  power  of  the  capitalist  to  dispense  with  the  artificial 
protection  of  gild  and  borough  and  carve  his  own  career.8 
"No  one  can  deny,"  wrote  the  foreign  merchants  at  Antwerp 
to  Phillip  II,  in  protest  against  an  attempt  to  interfere  with 
the  liberty  of  exchange  transactions,  "that  the  cause  of  the 
prosperity  of  this  city  is  the  freedom  granted  to  those  who 
trade  there  "  '*  Swept  into  wealth  on  the  crest  of  a  wave  of 
swiftly  expanding  enterprise,  which  a  century  before  would 
have  seemed  the  wildest  of  fantasies,  the  liberal  bourgeosie 
of  Antwerp  pursued,  in  the  teeth  of  all  precedents,  a  policy 
of  practical  individualism,  which  would  have  been  met  in  any 
other  city  by  rebellion,  making  terms  with  the  levelling  en- 
croachments of  the  Burgundian  monarchy,  which  were  fought 


THE    ECONOMIC   REVOLUTION  69 

by  their  more  conservative  neighbors,  lowering  tariffs  and  ex- 
tinguishing private  tolls,  welcoming  the  technical  improve- 
ments which  elsewhere  were  resisted,  taming  the  turbulent 
independence  of  the  gilds,  and  throwing  open  to  alien  and 
citizen  alike  the  new  Exchange,  with  its  significant  dedica- 
tion: Ad  usum  mercatorum  cuiusquc  gentis  ac  linguae. 

For,  if  Antwerp  was  the  microcosm  which  reflected  the 
soul  of  commercial  Europe,  the  heart  of  Antwerp  was  its 
Bourse.  The  causes  which  made  financial  capitalism  as  char- 
acteristic of  the  age  of  the  Renaissance,  as  industrial  capital- 
ism was  to  be  of  the  nineteenth  century,  consisted  partly  in 
the  mere  expansion  in  the  scale  of  commercial  enterprise.  A 
steady  flow  of  capital  was  needed  to  finance  the  movement 
of  the  produce  handled  on  the  world-market,  such  as  the 
eastern  spice  crop— above  all  pepper,  which  the  impecunious 
Portuguese  Government  sold  in  bulk,  while  it  was  still  on  the 
water,  to  German  syndicates — copper,  alum,  the  precious 
metals,  and  the  cloth  shipped  by  the  English  Merchant  Ad- 
venturers. The  cheapening  of  bullion  and  the  rise  in  prices 
welled  the  profits  seeking  investment;  the  growth  of  an  in- 
ternational banking  system  mobilized  immense  resources  at 
the  strategic  points;  and,  since  Antwerp  was  the  capital  of 
the  European  money-market,  the  bill  on  Antwerp  was  the 
commonest  form  of  international  currency.  Linked  together 
by  the  presence  in  each  of  the  great  financial  houses  of  the 
Continent,  with  liquid  funds  pouring  in  from  mines  in  Hun- 
gary and  the  Tyrol,  trading  ventures  in  the  East,  taxes  wrung 
from  Spanish  peasants,  speculations  on  the  part  of  financiers, 
and  savings  invested  by  the  general  public,  Antwerp,  Lyons, 
Frankfurt  and  Venice,  and,  in  the  second  rank,  Rouen, 
Strassburg,  Seville  and  London,  had  developed  by  the  middle 
of  the  century  a  considerable  class  of  financial  specialists, 
and  a  financial  technique,  identical,  in  all  essentials,  with 
that  of  the  present  day.  They  formed  together  the  depart- 
ments of  an  international  clearing-house,  where  bills  could 
be  readily  discounted,  drafts  on  any  important  city  could  be 
obtained,  and  the  paper  of  merchants  of  almost  every  na- 
tionality changed  hands.10 

Nourished  by  the  growth  of  peaceful  commerce,  the  finan- 
cial capitalism  of  the  age  fared  not  less  sumptuously,  if  more 
dangerously,  at  the  courts  of  princes  Mankind,  it  seems, 
hates  nothing  so  much  as  its  own  prosperity.  Menaced  with 
an  accession  of  riches  which  would  lighten  its  toil,  it  makes 


70  THE    CONTINENTAL    REFORMERS 

haste  to  redouble  its  labors,  and  to  pour  away  the  perilous 
stuff,  whcih  might  deprive  of  plausibility  the  complaint  that 
it  is  poor.  Applied  to  the  arts  of  peace,  the  new  resources 
commanded  by  Europe  during  the  first  half  of  the  sixteenth 
century  might  have  done  something  to  exorcise  the  specters 
of  pestilence  and  famine,  and  to  raise  the  material  fabric  of 
civilization  to  undreamed-of  heights  Its  rulers,  secular  and 
ecclesiastical  alike,  thought  otherwise  When  pestilence  and 
famine  were  ceasing  to  be  necessities  imposed  by  nature,  they 
reestablished  them  by  political  art 

The  sluice  which  they  opened  to  drain  away  each  new  ac- 
cession of  superfluous  wealth  was  war.  ct()f  all  birds,"  wrote 
the  sharpest  pen  of  the  age,  uthe  eagle  alone  has  seemed  to 
wise  men  the  type  of  royalty — not  beautiful,  not  musical, 
not  fit  for  food,  but  carnivorous,  greedy,  hateful  to  all,  the 
curse  of  all,  and,  with  its  great  powers  of  doing  harm,  sur- 
passing them  all  in  its  desire  of  doing  it  "  n  The  words  of 
Erasmus,  uttered  in  1517,  were  only  too  prophetic  For  ap- 
proximately three-quarters  both  of  the  sixteenth  and  of  the 
seventeenth  centuries,  Europe  tore  itself  to  pieces  In  the 
course  of  the  conflict  the  spiritual  fires  of  Renaissance  and 
Reformation  alike  were  trampled  out  beneath  the  feet  of  bra- 
vos  as  malicious  and  mischievous  as  the  vain,  bloody-minded 
and  futile  generals  who  strut  and  posture,  to  the  hateful 
laughter  of  Thersites,  in  the  most  despairing  of  Shakespeare's 
tragedies  By  the  middle  of  the  sixteenth  century  the  English 
Government,  after  an  orgy  of  debasement  and  confiscation, 
was  in  a  state  of  financial  collapse,  and  by  the  end  of  it 
Spain,  the  southern  Netherlands  including  Antwerp,  and  a 
great  part  of  France,  including  the  financial  capital  of  south- 
ern Europe,  Lyons,  were  ruined.  By  the  middle  of  the  seven- 
teenth century  wide  tracts  of  Germany  were  a  desert,  and  by 
the  end  of  it  the  French  finances  had  relapsed  into  worse 
confusion  than  that  from  which  they  had  been  temporarily 
rescued  by  the  genius  of  Colbert.  The  victors  compared  their 
position  with  that  of  the  vanquished,  and  congratulated 
themselves  on  their  spoils  It  rarely  occurred  to  them  to  ask 
what  it  would  have  been,  had  there  been  neither  victors  nor 
vanquished,  but  only  peace 

It  is  possible  that  the  bankruptcies  of  Governments  have, 
on  the  whole,  done  less  harm  to  mankind  than  their  ability 
to  raise  loans,  and  the  mobilization  of  economic  power  on  a 
scale  unknown  before  armed  the  fierce  nationalism  of  the  age 


THE   ECONOMIC   REVOLUTION  71 

with  a  weapon  more  deadly  than  gunpowder  and  cannon.  The 
centralized  States  which  were  rising  in  the  age  of  the  Renais- 
sance were  everywhere  faced  with  a  desperate  financial  sit- 
uation. It  sprang  from  the  combination  of  modern  adminis- 
trative and  military  methods  with  medieval  systems  of 
finance.  They  entrusted  to  bureaucracies  work  which,  if  done 
at  all,  had  formerly  been  done  as  an  incident  of  tenure,  or  by 
boroughs  and  gilds;  officials  had  to  be  paid.  They  were  con- 
stantly at  war,  and  the  new  technique  of  war,  involving  the 
use  of  masses  of  professional  infantry  and  artillery — which 
Rabelais  said  was  invented  by  the  inspiration  of  the  devil,  as 
a  counterpoise  to  the  invention  of  printing  inspired  by  God — 
was  making  it,  after  1870,  a  highly  capitalized  industry. 
Government  after  Government,  undeterred,  with  rare  excep- 
tions, by  the  disasters  of  its  neighbors,  trod  a  familiar  round 
of  expedients,  each  of  which  was  more  disastrous  than  the 
last.  They  hoarded  treasure,  only  to  see  the  accumulations 
of  a  thrifty  Henry  VII  or  Frederick  III  dissipated  by  a  Henry 
VIII  or  a  Maximilian.  They  debased  the  currency  and  ruined 
trade  They  sold  offices,  or  established  monopolies,  and 
crushed  the  taxpayer  beneath  a  load  of  indirect  taxation. 
They  plundered  the  Church,  and  spent  gorgeously  as  income 
property  which  should  have  been  treated  as  capital.  They 
parted  with  Crown  estates,  and  left  an  insoluble  problem  to 
their  successors. 

These  agreeable  devices  had,  however,  obvious  limits. 
What  remained,  when  they  were  exhausted,  was  the  money- 
market,  and  to  the  rulers  of  the  money-market  sooner  or  later 
all  States  came  Their  dependence  on  the  financier  was  thnt 
of  an  Ismail  or  an  Abdul,  and  its  results  were  not  less  disas- 
trous. Naturally,  the  City  interest  was  one  of  the  great  Pow- 
ers of  Europe.  Publicists  might  write  that  the  new  Messiah 
was  the  Prince,  and  reformers  that  the  Prince  was  Pope.  But 
behind  Prince  and  Pope  alike,  financing  impartially  Henry 
VIII,  Edward  VI  and  Elizabeth,  Francis,  Charles  and  Philip, 
stood  in  the  last  resort  a  little  German  banker,  with  branches 
in  every  capital  in  Europe,  who  played  in  the  world  of  fi- 
nance the  part  of  the  condottieri  in  war,  and  represented  in 
the  economic  sphere  the  morality  typified  in  that  of  politics 
by  Machiavelli's  Prince.  Compared  with  these  financial  dy- 
nasties, Hapsburgs,  Valois  and  Tudors  were  puppets  dancing 
on  wires  held  by  a  money-power  to  which  political  struggles 
were  irrelevant  except  as  an  opportunity  for  gain. 


72  THE    CONTINENTAL   REFORMERS 

The  financier  received  his  payment  in  cash,  partly  in  con- 
cessions, which  still  further  elaborated  the  network  of  finan- 
cial connections  that  were  making  Europe  an  economic  unity. 
The  range  of  interests  in  which  the  German  banking  houses 
were  involved  is  astonishing.  The  Welsers  had  invested  in 
the  Portuguese  voyage  of  1505  to  the  East  Indies,  financed 
an  expedition,  half  commercial,  half  military,  to  Venezuela 
in  1527,  were  engaged  in  the  spice  trade  between  Lisbon, 
Antwerp  and  south  Germany,  were  partners  in  silver  and 
copper  mines  in  the  Tyrol  and  Hungary,  and  had  establish- 
ments, not  only  at  Lisbon  and  Antwerp,  but  in  the  principal 
cities  of  Germany,  Italy  and  Switzerland  The  careers  of  the 
Hochstetters,  Haugs,  Meutings  and  Tmhofs  were  much  the 
same.  The  Fuggers,  thanks  to  judicious  loans  to  Maximilian, 
had  acquired  enormous  concessions  of  mineral  property, 
farmed  a  large  part  of  the  receipts  drawn  by  the  Spanish 
Crown  from  its  estates,  held  silver  and  quicksilver  mines  in 
Spain,  and  controlled  banking  and  commercial  businesses  in 
Italy,  and,  above  all,  at  Antwerp.  They  advanced  the  money 
which  made  Albrecht  of  Brandenburg  archbishop  of  Mainz; 
repaid  themselves  by  sending  their  agent  to  accompany  Tet- 
zel  on  his  campaign  to  raise  money  by  indulgences  and  tak- 
ing half  the  proceeds;  provided  the  funds  with  which  Charles 
V  bought  the  imperial  crown,  after  an  election  conducted 
with  the  publicity  of  an  auction  and  the  morals  of  a  gambling 
hell;  browbeat  him,  when  the  debt  was  not  paid,  in  the  tone 
of  a  pawnbroker  rating  a  necessitous  client;  and  found  the 
money  with  which  Charles  raised  troops  to  fight  the  Prot- 
estants in  1552  The  head  of  the  firm  built  a  church  and  en- 
dowed an  almshouse  for  the  aged  poor  in  his  native  town  of 
Augsburg.  He  died  in  the  odor  of  sanctity,  a  good  Catholic 
and  a  Count  of  the  Empire,  having  seen  his  firm  pay  54  per 
cent,  for  the  preceding  sixteen  years. 1J 

II     LUTHER 

Like  the  rise  of  a  great  industry  three  centuries  later,  the 
economic  revolution  which  accompanied  the  Renaissance 
gave  a  powerful  stimulus  to  speculation.  Both  in  Germany 
andJp  England,  the  Humanists  turned^a  stream  ot  pungent 
rritirfen^y*-*^^  ot  their  age?  M^fiatitiliS't  think- 

ers  resharpened  anold  economic  weapon  for  the  armory  of 
princes.  Objective  economic  analysis,  still  in  its  infancy,  re- 


LUTHER  73 

ceived  a  new  impetus  from  the  controversies  of  practical  men 
on  the  rise  in  prices,  on  currency,  and  on  the  foreign  ex- 
changes. 

The  question  of  the  attitude  which  religious  opinion  would 
assume  towards  these  new  forces  was  momentous.  It  might 
hail  the  outburst  of  economic  enterprise  as  an  instrument  of 
wealth  and  luxury,  like  the  Popes  who  revelled  in  the  redis- 
covery of  classical  culture.  It  might  denounce  it  as  a  relapse 
into  a  pagan  immorality,  like  the  Fathers  who  had  turned 
with  a  shudder  from  the  material  triumphs  of  Rome.  It  might 
attempt  to  harness  the  expanding  energies  to  its  own  concep- 
tion of  man's  spiritual  end,  like  the  Schoolmen  who  had 
stretched  old  formulae  to  cover  the  new  forces  of  capital  and 
commerce.  It  could  hardly  ignore  them  For,  in  spite  of  Ma- 
chiavelli,  social  theory  was  only  beginning  to  emancipate  it- 
self from  the  stiff  ecclesiastical  framework  of  the  Middle 
Ages  The  most  systematic  treatment  of  economic  questions 
was  still  that  contained  in  the  work  of  canonists,  and  divines 
continued  to  pronounce  judgment  on  problems  of  property 
and  contract  with  the  same  assurance  as  on  problems  of 

theology. 

Laymen  might  dispute  the  content  of  their  teaching  and 
defy  its  conclusions  But  it  was  rarely,  as  yet,  that  they  at- 
tacked the  assumption  that  questions  of  economic  conduct 
belonged  to  the  province  of  the  ecclesiastical  jurist  Bellar- 
min  complained  with  some  asperity  of  the  intolerable  com- 
plexity of  the  problems  of  economic  casuistry  which  pious 
merchants  propounded  in  the  confessional.  The  Spanish  deal- 
ers on  the  Antwerp  Bourse,  a  class  not  morbidly  prone  to 
conscientious  scruples,  were  sufficiently  deferential  to  ecclesi- 
astical authority  to  send  their  confessor  to  Paris  in  order  to 
consult  the  theologians  of  the  University  as  to  the  compati- 
bility of  speculative  exchange  business  with  the  canon  law.1'* 
When  Eck,  later  famous  as  the  champion  who  crossed  swords 
with  Luther,  travelled  to  Italy,  in  order  to  seek  from  the 
University  of  Bologna  authoritative  confirmation  of  his  dar- 
ing argument  that  interest  could  lawfully  be  charged  in  trans- 
actions between  merchants,  no  less  a  group  of  capitalists 
than  the  great  house  of  Fugger  thought  it  worth  while  to  fi- 
nance an  expedition  undertaken  in  quest  of  so  profitable  a 

truth  14 

Individualistic,  competitive,  swept  forward  by  an  immense 
expansion  of  commerce  and  finance,  rather  than  of  industry 


74  THE  CONTINENTAL  REFORMERS 

and  offering  opportunities  of  speculative  gain  on  a  scale  un- 
known before,  the  new  economic  civilization  inevitably  gave 
rise  to  passionate  controversy;  and  inevitably,  since  both  the 
friends  and  enemies  of  the  Reformation  identified  it  with  so- 
cial change,  the  leaders  in  the  religious  struggle  were  the  pro- 
tagonists in  the  debate.  In  Germany,  where  social  revolution 
had  been  fermenting  for  half  a  century,  it  seemed  at  last  to 
have  come.  The  rise  in  prices,  an  enigma  which  baffled  con- 
temporaries till  Bodin  published  his  celebrated  tract  in 
1S69,15  produced  a  storm  of  indignation  against  monopolists. 
Since  the  rising  led  by  Hans  Boheim  in  1476,  hardly  a  dec- 
ade had  passed  without  a  peasants '  revolt.  Usury,  long  a 
grievance  with  craftsman  and  peasant,  had  become  a  battle- 
cry.  From  city  after  city  municipal  authorities,  terrified  by 
popular  demands  for  the  repression  of  the  extortioner,  con- 
sulted universities  and  divines  as  to  the  legitimacy  of  inter- 
est, and  universities  and  divines  gave,  as  is  their  wont,  a 
loud,  but  confused,  response.  Melanchthon  expounded  godly 
doctrine  on  the  subject  of  money-lending  and  prices.16  Calvin 
wrote  a  famous  letter  on  usury  and  delivered  sermons  on  the 
same  subject.17  Bucer  sketched  a  scheme  of  social  recon- 
struction for  a  Christian  prince.18  Bullinger  produced  a  clas- 
sical exposition  of  social  ethics  in  the  Decades  which  he 
dedicated  to  Edward  VI. r'  Luther  preached  and  pamphle- 
teered against  extortioners,20  and  said  that  it  was  time  "to 
put  a  bit  in  the  mouth  of  the  holy  company  of  the  Fug- 
gers."  21  Zwingli  and  Oecolampadius  devised  plans  for  the 
reorganization  of  poor  relief.22  Above  all,  the  Peasants'  War, 
with  its  touching  appeal  to  the  Gospel  and  its  frightful  ca- 
tastrophe, not  only  terrified  Luther  into  his  outburst:  "Who- 
so can,  strike,  smite,  strangle,  or  stab,  secretly  or  publicly 
.  .  .  such  wonderful  times  are  these  that  a  prince  can  better 
merit  Heaven  with  bloodshed  than  another  with  prayer";23 
it  also  helped  to  stamp  on  Lutheranism  an  almost  servile  re- 
liance on  the  secular  authorities.  In  England  there  was  less 
violence,  but  hardly  less  agitation,  and  a  similar  flood  of  writ- 
ing and  preaching.  Latimer,  Ponet,  Crowley,  Lever,  Becon, 
Sandys  and  Jewel — to  mention  but  the  best-known  names — 
all  contributed  to  the  debate.24  Whatever  the  social  practice 
of  the  sixteenth  century  may  have  been,  it  did  not  suffer  for 
lack  of  social  teaching  on  the  part  of  men  of  religion.  If  the 
world  could  be  saved  by  sermons  and  pamphlets,  it  would 
have  been  a  Paradise. 


LUTHER  75 

That  the  problems  of  a  swiftly  changing  economic  en- 
vironment should  have  burst  on  Europe  at  a  moment  when 
it  was  torn  by  religious  dissensions  more  acute  than  ever  be* 
fore,  may  perhaps  be  counted  as  not  least  among  the  trage- 
dies of  its  history.  But  differences  of  social  theory  did  not 
coincide  with  differences  of  religious  opinion,  and  the  mark 
of  nearly  all  this  body  of  teaching,  alike  in  Germany  and  in 
England,  is  its  conservatism.  Where  questions  of  social  mo- 
rality were  involved,  men  whose  names  are  a  symbol  of  re- 
ligious revolution  stood,  with  hardly  an  exception,  on  the 
ancient  ways,  appealed  to  medieval  authorities,  and  repro- 
duced in  popular  language  the  doctrines  of  the  Schoolmen. 

A  view  of  the  social  history  of  the  sixteenth  century  which 
has  found  acceptance  in  certain  quarters  has  represented  the 
Reformation  as  the  triumph  of  the  commercial  spirit  over  the 
traditional  social  ethics  of  Christendom  Something  like  it  is 
of  respectable  antiquity.  As  early  as  1540  Cranmer  wrote  to 
Oziander  protesting  against  the  embarrassment  caused  to  re- 
formers in  England  by  the  indulgence  to  moral  laxity,  in  the 
matter  alike  of  economic  transactions  and  of  marriage,  al- 
leged to  be  given  by  reformers  in  Germany. ^  By  the  seven- 
teenth century  the  hints  had  become  a  theory  and  an  argu- 
ment. Bonnet  taunted  Calvin  and  Bucer  with  being  the  first 
theologians  to  defend  extortion,20  and  it  only  remained  for 
a  pamphleteer  to  adapt  the  indictment  to  popular  consump- 
tion, by  writing  bluntly  that  "it  grew  to  a  proverb  that 
usury  was  the  brat  of  heresy  "27  That  the  revolt  from  Rome 
synchronized,  both  in  Germany  and  in  England,  with  a  pe- 
riod of  acute  social  distress  is  undeniable,  nor  is  any  long 
argument  needed  to  show  that,  like  other  revolutions,  it  had 
its  seamy  side  What  is  sometimes  suggested,  however,  is  not 
merely  a  coincidence  of  religious  and  economic  movements, 
but  a  logical  connection  between  changes  in  economic  or- 
ganization and  changes  in  religious  doctrines.  It  is  implied 
that  the  bad  social  practice  of  the  age  was  the  inevitable  ex- 
pression of  its  religious  innovations,  and  that,  if  the  reform- 
ers did  not  explicitly  teach  a  conscienceless  individualism, 
individualism  was,  at  least,  the  natural  corollary  of  their 
teaching  In  the  eighteenth  century,  which  had  as  little  love 
for  the  commercial  restrictions  of  the  ages  of  monkish  super- 
stition as  for  their  political  theory,  that  view  was  advanced 
as  eulogy.  In  our  own  day,  the  wheel  seems  almost  to  have 
come  full  circle.  What  was  then  a  matter  for  congratulation 


76  THE    CONTINENTAL   REFORMERS 

is  now  often  an  occasion  for  criticism.  There  are  writers  by 
whom  the  Reformation  is  attacked,  as  inaugurating  a  period 
of  unscrupulous  commercialism,  which  had  previously  been 
held  in  check,  it  is  suggested,  by  the  teaching  of  the  Church. 

These  attempts  to  relate  changes  in  social  theory  to  the 
grand  religious  struggles  of  the  age  have  their  significance. 
But  the  obiter  dicta  of  an  acrimonious  controversy  throw 
more  light  on  the  temper  of  the  combatants  than  on  the  sub- 
stance of  their  contentions,  and  the  issues  were  too  complex 
to  be  adequately  expressed  in  the  simple  antitheses  which 
appealed  to  partisans.  If  capitalism  means  the  direction  of 
industry  by  the  owners  of  capital  for  their  own  pecuniary 
gain,  and  the  social  relationships  which  establish  themselves 
Between  them  and  the  wage-earning  proletariat  whom  they 
control,  then  capitalism  had  existed  on  a  grand  scale  both  in 
medieval  Italy  and  in  medieval  Flanders.  If  by  the  capitalist 
spirit  is  meant  the  temper  which  is  prepared  to  sacrifice  all 
moral  scruples  to  the  pursuit  of  profit,  it  had  been  only  too 
familiar  to  the  saints  and  sages  of  the  Middle  Ages  It  was 
the  economic  imperialism  of  Catholic  Portugal  and  Spain, 
not  the  less  imposing,  if  more  solid,  achievements  of  the 
Protestant  powers,  which  impressed  contemporaries  down  to 
the  Armada.  It  was  predominantly  Catholic  cities  which 
were  the  commercial  capitals  of  Europe,  and  Catholic  bank- 
ers who  were  its  leading  financiers. 

Nor  is  the  suggestion  that  Protestant  opinion  looked  with 
indulgence  on  the  temper  which  attacked  restraints  on  eco- 
nomic enterprise  better  founded  If  it  is  true  that  the  Refor- 
mation released  forces  which  were  to  act  as  a  solvent  of  the 
traditional  attitude  of  religious  thought  to  social  and  eco- 
nomic issues,  it  did  so  without  design,  and  against  the  inten- 
tion of  most  reformers  In  reality,  however  sensational  the 
innovations  in  economic  practice  which  accompanied  the  ex- 
pansion of  financial  capitalism  in  the  sixteenth  century,  the 
development  of  doctrine  on  the  subject  of  economic  ethics 
was  continuous,  and,  the  more  closely  it  is  examined,  the  less 
foundation  does  there  seem  to  be  for  the  view  that  the  stream 
plunged  into  vacancy  over  the  precipice  of  the  religious  revo- 
lution. To  think  of  the  abdication  of  religion  from  its  theo- 
retical primacy  over  economic  activity  and  social  institutions 
as  synchronizing  with  the  revolt  from  Rome,  is  to  antedate  a 
movement  which  was  not  finally  accomplished  for  another 
century  and  a  half,  and  which  owed  as  much  to  changes  in 


LUTHER  77 

economic  and  political  organization,  as  it  did  to  develop- 
ments in  the  sphere  of  religious  thought.  In  the  sixteenth 
century  religious  teachers  of  all  shades  of  opinion  still 
searched  the  Bible,  the  Fathers  and  the  Corpus  Juris  Ca- 
nonici  for  light  on  practical  questions  of  social  morality,  and, 
as  far  as  the  first  generation  of  reformers  was  concerned, 
there  was  no  intention,  among  either  Lutherans,  or  Calvin- 
ists,  or  Anglicans,  of  relaxing  the  rules  of  good  conscience, 
which  were  supposed  to  control  economic  transactions  and 
social  relations.  If  anything,  indeed,  their  tendency  was  to  in- 
terpret them  with  a  more  rigorous  severity,  as  a  protest 
against  the  moral  laxity  of  the  Renaissance,  and,  in  partic- 
ular, against  the  avarice  which  was  thought  to  be  peculiarly 
the  sin  of  Rome.  For  the  passion  for  regeneration  and  puri- 
fication, which  was  one  element  in  the  Reformation,  was  di- 
rected against  the  corruption  of  society  as  well  as  of  the 
Church.  Princes  and  nobles  and  business  men  conducted 
themselves  after  their  kind,  and  fished  eagerly  in  troubled 
waters  But  the  aim  of  religious  leaders  was  to  reconstruct, 
not  merely  doctrine  and  ecclesiastical  government,  but  con- 
duct and  institutions,  on  a  pattern  derived  from  the  forgotten 
purity  of  primitive  Christianity 

The  appeal  from  the  depravity  of  the  present  to  a  golden 
age  of  pristine  innocence  found  at  once  its  most  vehement, 
and  its  most  artless,  expression  in  the  writings  of  the  German 
reformers.  Like  the  return  to  nature  in  the  eighteenth  cen- 
tury, it  was  the  cry  for  spiritual  peace  of  a  society  disillu- 
sioned with  the  material  triumphs  of  a  too  complex  civiliza- 
tion The  prosperity  of  Augsburg,  Nurnberg,  Regcnsburg, 
Ulm  and  Frankfurt,  and  even  of  lesser  cities  like  Rotenburg 
and  Freiburg,  had  long  been  the  admiration  of  all  observers. 
Commanding  the  great  trade  routes  across  the  Alps  and  down 
the  Rhine,  they  had  held  a  central  position,  which  they  were 
to  lose  when  the  spice  trade  moved  to  Antwerp  and  Lisbon, 
and  were  not  to  recover  till  the  creation  of  a  railway  system 
in  the  nineteenth  century  made  Germany  again  the  entrepot 
between  western  Europe  and  Russia,  Austria,  Italy  and  the 
near  East  But  the  expansion  of  commerce,  which  brought 
affluence  to  the  richer  bourgeoisie,  had  been  accompanied  by 
the  growth  of  an  acute  social  malaise,  which  left  its  mark  on 
literature  and  popular  agitation,  even  before  the  Discoveries 
turned  Germany  from  a  highway  into  a  back-water.  The 
economic  aspect  of  the  development  was  the  rise  to  a  posi- 


78  THE    CONTINENTAL    REFORMERS 

tion  of  overwhelming  preeminence  of  the  new  interests  based 
on  the  control  of  capital  and  credit.  In  the  earlier  Middle 
Ages  capital  had  been  the  adjunct  and  ally  of  the  personal 
labor  of  craftsman  and  artisan.  In  the  Germany  of  the  fif- 
teenth century,  as  long  before  in  Italy,  it  had  ceased  to  be 
a  servant  and  had  become  a  master.  Assuming  a  separate 
and  independent  vitality,  it  claimed  the  right  of  a  predom- 
inant partner  to  dictate  economic  organization  in  accordance 
with  its  own  exacting  requirements. 

Under  the  impact  of  these  new  forces,  while  the  institu- 
tions of  earlier  ages  survived  in  form,  their  spirit  and  opera- 
tion were  transformed.  In  the  larger  cities  the  gild  organiza- 
tion, once  a  barrier  to  the  encroachments  of  the  capitalist, 
became  one  of  the  instruments  which  he  used  to  consolidate 
his  power.  The  rules  of  fraternities  masked  a  division  of  the 
brethren  into  a  plutocracy  of  merchants,  sheltered  behind 
barriers  which  none  but  the  wealthy  craftsman  could  scale, 
and  a  wage-earning  proletariat,  dependent  for  their  liveli- 
hood on  capital  and  credit  supplied  by  their  masters,  and 
alternately  rising  in  revolt  and  sinking  in  an  ever-expanding 
morass  of  hopeless  pauperism 28  The  peasantry  suffered 
equally  from  the  spread  of  a  commercial  civilization  into  the 
rural  districts  and  from  the  survival  of  ancient  agtarian 
servitudes  As  in  England,  the  nouveaux  riches  of  fhe  towns 
invested  money  in  land  by  purchase  and  loan,  and  drove  up 
rents  and  fines  by  their  competition  But,  while  in  England 
the  customary  tenant  was  shaking  off  the  onerous  obliga- 
tions of  villeinage,  and  appealing,  not  without  success,  to 
the  royal  courts  to  protect  his  title,  his  brother  in  south 
Germany,  where  serfdom  was  to  last  till  the  middle  of  the 
nineteenth  century,  found  corvecs  redoubled  money-pay- 
ments increased,  and  common  rights  curtailed,  for  the  bene- 
fit of  an  improverished  nobles se,  which  saw  in  the  exploita- 
tion of  the  peasant  the  only  means  of  maintaining  its  social 
position  in  face  of  the  rapidly  growing  wealth  of  the  bour- 
geoisie, and  which  seized  on  the  now  fashionable  Roman 
law  as  an  instrument  to  give  legal  sanction  to  its  harshest 
exactions.29 

On  a  society  thus  distracted  by  the  pains  of  growth  came 
the  commercial  revolution  produced  by  the  Discoveries. 
Their  effect  was  to  open  a  seemingly  limitless  field  to  eco- 
nomic enterprise,  and  to  sharpen  the  edge  of  every  social 
problem.  Unable  henceforward  to  tap  through  Venice  the 


LUTHER  70 

wealth  of  the  East,  the  leading  commercial  houses  of  south 
Germany  either  withdrew  from  the  trade  across  the  Alps,  to 
specialize,  like  the  Fuggers,  in  banking  and  finance,  or  or* 
ganized  themselves  into  companies,  which  handled  at  Lisbon 
and  Antwerp  a  trade  too  distant  and  too  expensive  to  be 
undertaken  by  individual  merchants  using  only  their  own 
resources.  The  modern  world  has  seen  in  America  the  swift 
rise  of  combinations  controlling  output  and  prices  by  the 
power  of  massed  capital.  A  somewhat  similar  movement  took 
place  on  the  narrower  stage  of  European  commerce  in  the 
generation  before  the  Reformation.  Its  center  was  Germany, 
and  it  was  defended  and  attacked  by  arguments  almost  iden- 
tical with  those  which  are  familiar  today.  The  exactions  of 
rings  and  monopolies,  which  bought  in  bulk,  drove  weaker 
competitors  out  of  the  field,  "as  a  great  pike  swallows  up 
a  lot  of  little  fishes/'  and  plundered  the  consumer,  were  the 
commonplaces  of  the  social  reformer/0  The  advantages  of 
large-scale  organization  and  the  danger  of  interfering  with 
freedom  of  enterprise  were  urged  by  the  companies.  The 
problem  was  on  several  occasions  brought  before  the  Im- 
perial Diet.  But  the  discovery  of  the  sage  who  observed 
that  it  is  not  possible  to  unscramble  eggs  had  already  been 
made,  and  its  decrees,  passed  in  the  teeth  of  strenuous  op- 
position from  the  interests  concerned,  do  not  seem  to  have 
been  more  effective  than  modern  legislation  on  the  same 
subject. 

The  passionate  anti-capitalist  reaction  which  such  condi- 
tions produced  found  expression  in  numerous  schemes  of 
social  reconstruction,  from  the  so-called  Reformation  of  the 
Emperor  Sigismund  in  the  thirties  of  the  fifteenth  century, 
to  the  Twelve  Articles  of  the  peasants  in  1525  jl  In  the  age 
of  the  Reformation  it  was  voiced  by  Hipler,  who,  in  his 
Divine  Evangelical  Reformation,  urged  that  all  merchants' 
companies,  such  as  those  of  the  Fuggers,  Hochstetters  and 
Welsers,  should  be  abolished,  by  Hutten,  who  classed  mer- 
chants with  knights,  lawyers  and  the  clergy  as  public 
robbers;  by  Geiler  von  Kaiser  berg,  who  wrote  that  the 
monopolists  were  more  detestable  than  Jews,  and  should  b€ 
exterminated  like  wolves;  and,  above  all,  by  Luther.32 

Luther's  utterances  on  social  morality  are  the  occasional 
explosions  of  a  capricious  volcano,  with  only  a  rare  flash  of 
light  amid  the  torrent  of  smoke  and  flame,  and  it  is  idle  tq 


80  THE    CONTINENTAL   REFORMERS 

scan  them  for  a  coherent  and  consistent  doctrine.  Compared 
with  the  lucid  and  subtle  rationalism  of  a  thinker  like  St. 
Antonio,  his  sermons  and  pamphlets  on  social  questions 
make  an  impression  of  naivete,  as  of  an  impetuous  but  ill- 
informed  genius,  dispensing  with  the  cumbrous  embarrass- 
ments of  law  and  logic,  to  evolve  a  system  of  social  ethics 
from  the  inspired  heat  of  his  own  unsophisticated  conscious- 
ness. 

It  was  partly  that  they  were  pieces  de  cir  con  stance,  thrown 
off  in  the  storm  of  a  revolution,  partly  that  it  was  precisely 
the  refinements  of  law  and  logic  which  Luther  detested. 
Confronted  with  the  complexities  of  foreign  trade  and  finan- 
cial organization,  or  with  the  subtleties  of  economic  analysis, 
he  is  like  a  savage  introduced  to  a  dynamo  or  a  steam-engine. 
He  is  too  frightened  and  angry  even  to  feel  curiosity.  At- 
tempts to  explain  the  mechanism  merely  enrage  him;  he  can 
only  repeat  that  there  is  a  devil  in  it,  and  that  good  Chris- 
tians will  not  meddle  with  the  mystery  of  iniquity  Bui 
there  is  a  method  in  his  fury  It  sprang,  not  from  ignorance, 
for  he  was  versed  in  scholastic  philosophy,  but  from  a  con- 
ception which  made  the  learning  of  the  schools  appear  trivial 
or  mischievous. 

"Gold,"  wrote  Columbus,  as  one  enunciating  a  truism, 
"constitutes  treasure,  and  he  who  possesses  it  has  all  the 
needs  in  this  world,  as  also  the  means  of  rescuing  souls  from 
Purgatory,  and  restoring  them  to  the  enjoyment  of  Para- 
dise." 3^  It  was  this  doctrine  that  all  things  have  their  price 
— future  salvation  as  much  as  present  felicity — which  scan- 
dalized men  who  could  not  be  suspected  of  disloyalty  to  the 
Church,  and  which  gave  their  most  powerful  argument  to  the 
reformers.  Their  outlook  on  society  had  this  in  common 
with  their  outlook  on  religion,  that  the  essence  of  both  was 
the  arraignment  of  a  degenerate  civilization  before  the  ma- 
jestic bar  of  an  uncorrupted  past  Of  that  revolutionary 
conservatism  Luther,  who  hated  the  economic  individualism 
of  the  age  not  less  than  its  spiritual  laxity,  is  the  supreme 
example.  His  attitude  to  the  conquest  of  society  by  the 
merchant  and  financier  is  the  same  as  his  attitude  towards 
the  commercialization  of  religion.  When  he  looks  at  the 
Church  in  Germany,  he  sees  it  sucked  dry  by  the  tribute 
which  flows  to  the  new  Babylon.  When  he  looks  at  German 
social  life,  he  finds  it  ridden  by  a  conscienceless  money- 


LUTHER  81 

power,  which  incidentally  ministers,  like  the  banking  busi- 
ness of  the  Fuggers,  to  the  avarice  and  corruption  of  Rome* 
The  exploitation  of  the  Church  by  the  Papacy,  and  th# 
exploitation  of  the  peasant  and  the  craftsman  by  the  cap- 
italist, are  thus  two  horns  of  the  beast  which  sits  on  the 
seven  hills  Both  are  essentially  pagan,  and  the  sword  which 
will  slay  both  is  the  same.  It  is  the  religion  of  the  Gospel. 
The  Church  must  cease  to  be  an  empire,  and  become  a  con- 
gregation of  believers  Renouncing  the  prizes  and  struggles 
which  make  the  heart  sick,  society  must  be  converted  into 
a  band  of  brothers,  performing  in  patient  cheerfulness  the 
round  of  simple  toil  which  is  the  common  lot  of  the  descend- 
ants of  Adam. 

The  children  of  the  mind  are  like  the  children  of  the  body. 
Once  born,  they  grow  by  a  law  of  their  own  being,  and,  if 
their  parents  could  foresee  their  future  development,  it  would 
sometimes  break  their  hearts  Luther,  who  has  earned  eu- 
logy and  denunciation  as  the  grand  individualist,  would 
have  been  horrified,  could  he  have  anticipated  the  remoter 
deductions  to  be  derived  from  his  argument.  Wamba  said 
that  to  forgive  as  a  Christian  is  not  to  forgive  at  all,  and 
a  cynic  who  urged  that  the  Christian  freedom  expounded 
by  Luther  imposed  more  social  restraints  than  it  removed 
would  have  more  affinity  with  the  thought  of  Luther  him- 
self, than  the  libertarian  who  saw  in  his  teaching  a  plea  for 
treating  questions  of  economic  conduct  and  social  organiza- 
tion as  sphitually  indifferent.^ Luther >  rpvnlt  ag.gi'nqfl_a.ii.. 
thority  was  an  attack,  not  on  its  rigor,  but  on  its  laxity  and 
its  corruption  His  individualism  was  not  the  greed  of  the 
plutocrat,  eagfer^tb  snatch  from  the  weakness  of  public  au- 
thority an  opportunity  for  personal  gain.  It  was  the^ngenu- 
mis  enthusiasm  of  the  anarchist,  who  hungers  for  a  society 
inwMCrl  order  jWd  fraternity  will  r^ign  without  "the  tedi- 
ous, stale,  forbidding  ways  of  custom,  law  and  statute?' 
because  they  well  up  in  all  theiF  native  purity  from  the 
heart. 

Professor  Troeltsch  has  pointed  out  that  Protestants,  not 
less  than  Catholics,  emphasized  the  idea  of  a  Church-civil- 
ization, in  which  all  departments  of  life,  the  State  and 
society,  education  and  science,  law,  commerce  and  industry, 
were  to  be  regulated  in  accordance  with  the  law  of  God.*4 
That  conception  dominates  all  the  utterances  of  Luther  on 


82  THE    CONTINENTAL    REFORMERS 

social  issues  So  far  from  accepting  the  view  which  was 
afterwards  to  prevail,  that  the  world  of  business  is  a  closed 
compartment  with  laws  of  its  own,  and  that  the  religious 
teacher  exceeds  his  commission  when  he  lays  down  rules  for 
the  moral  conduct  of  social  affairs,  he  reserves  for  that 
plausible  heresy  denunciations  hardly  less  bitter  than  those 
directed  against  Rome.  The  text  of  his  admonitions  is  al- 
ways, " Unless  your  righteousness  exceeds  that  of  the  Scribes 
and  Pharisees/'  and  his  appeal  is  from  a  formal,  legalistic, 
calculated  virtue  to  the  natural  kindliness  which  does  not 
need  to  be  organized  by  law,  because  it  is  the  spontaneous 
expression  of  a  habit  of  love.  To  restore  is  to  destroy.  The 
comment  on  Luther's  enthusiasm  for  the  simple  Christian 
virtues  of  an  age  innocent  of  the  artificial  chicaneries  of 
ecclesiastical  and  secular  jurisprudence  came  in  the  thunder 
of  revolution.  It  was  the  declaration  of  the  peasants,  that 
"the  message  of  Christ,  the  promised  Messiah,  the  word  of 
life,  teaching  only  love,  peace,  patience  and  concord,"  was 
incompatible  with  serfdom,  corvecs,  and  enclosures  ' 

The  practical  conclusion  to  which  such  premises  led  was 
a  theory  of  society  more  medieval  than  that  held  by  many 
thinkers  in  the  Middle  Ages,  since  it  dismissed  the  commer- 
cial developments  of  the  last  two  centuries  as  a  relapse  into 
paganism.  The  foundation  of  it  was  partly  the  Bible,  partly 
a  vague  conception  of  a  state  of  nature  in  which  men  had 
not  yet  been  corrupted  by  riches,  partly  the  popular  protests 
against  a  commercial  civilization  which  were  everywhere  in 
the  air,  and  which  Luther,  a  man  of  the  people,  absorbed 
and  reproduced  with  astonishing  naivete,  even  while  he  de- 
nounced the  practical  measures  proposed  to  give  effect  to 
them.  Like  some  elements  in  the  Catholic  reaction  of  the 
twentieth  century,  the  Protestant  reaction  of  the  sixteenth 
sighed  for  a  vanished  age  of  peasant  prosperity.  The  social 
theory  of  Luther,  who  hated  commerce  and  capitalism,  has 
its  nearest  modern  analogy  in  the  Distributive  State  of 
Mr.  Belloc  and  Mr.  Chesterton. 

For  the  arts  by  which  men  amass  wealth  and  power,  as 
for  the  anxious  provision  which  accumulates  for  the  future, 
Luther  had  all  the  distrust  of  a  peasant  and  a  monk.  Chris- 
tians should  earn  their  living  in  the  sweat  of  their  brow, 
take  no  thought  for  the  morrow,  marry  young  and  trust 
Heaven  to  provide  for  its  own.  Like  Melanchthon,  Luther 
thought  that  the  most  admirable  life  was  that  of  the  peasant, 


LUTHER  83 

for  it  was  least  touched  by  the  corroding  spirit  of  commer- 
cial calculation,  and  he  quoted  Virgil  to  drive  home  the 
lesson  to  be  derived  from  the  example  of  the  patriarchs.88 
The  labor  of  the  craftsman  is  honorable,  for  he  serves  the 
community  in  his  calling;  the  honest  smith  or  shoemaker  is 
a  priest.  Trade  is  permissible,  provided  that  it  is  confined 
to  the  exchange  of  necessaries,  and  that  the  seller  demands 
no  more  than  will  compensate  him  for  his  labor  and  risk. 
The  unforgivable  sins  are  idleness  and  covetousness,  for  they 
destroy  the  unity  of  the  body  of  which  Christians  are  mem- 
bers. The  grand  author  and  maintainer  of  both  is  Rome.  For, 
having  ruined  Italy,  the  successor  of  St.  Peter,  who  lives  in 
a  worldly  pomp  that  no  king  or  emperor  can  equal,  has 
fastened  his  fangs  on  Germany;  while  the  mendicant  orders, 
mischievous  alike  in  their  practice  and  by  their  example, 
cover  the  land  with  a  horde  of  beggars.  Pilgrimages,  saints' 
days  and  monasteries  are  an  excuse  for  idleness  and  must 
be  suppressed.  Vagrants  must  be  either  banished  or  com- 
pelled to  labor,  and  each  town  must  organize  charity  for 
the  support  of  the  honest  poor  3T 

Luther  accepted  the  social  hierachy,  with  its  principles  of 
status  and  subordination,  though  he  knocked  away  the  ec- 
clesiastical rungs  in  the  ladder.  The  combination  of  religious 
radicalism  and  economic  conservatism  is  not  uncommon, 
and  in  the  traditional  conception  of  society,  as  an  organism 
of  unequal  classes  with  different  rights  and  functions,  the 
father  of  all  later  revolutions  found  an  arsenal  of  arguments 
against  change,  which  he  launched  with  almost  equal  fury 
against  revolting  peasants  and  grasping  monopolists.  His 
vindication  of  the  spiritual  freedom  of  common  men,  and 
his  outspoken  abuse  of  the  German  princes,  had  naturally 
been  taken  at  their  face  value  by  serfs  groaning  under  an 
odious  tyranny,  and,  when  the  inevitable  rising  came,  the 
rage  of  Luther,  like  that  of  Burke  in  another  age,  was  sharp- 
ened by  embarrassment  at  what  seemed  to  him  a  hideous 
parody  of  truths  which  were  both  sacred  and  his  own.  As 
fully  convinced  as  any  medieval  writer  that  serfdom  was 
the  necessary  foundation  of  society,  his  alarm  at  the  attempt 
to  abolish  it  was  intensified  by  a  political  theory  which  ex- 
alted the  absolutism  of  secular  authorities,  and  a  religious 
doctrine  which  drew  a  sharp  antithesis  between  the  external 
order  and  the  life  of  the  spirit.  The  demand  of  the  peasants 


84  THE    CONTINENTAL    REFORMERS 

that  villeinage  should  end,  because  "  Christ  has  delivered  and 
redeemed  us  all,  the  lowly  as  well  as  the  great,  without  ex- 
ception, by  the  shedding  of  His  precious  blood,"  >>s  horrified 
him,  partly  as  portending  an  orgy  of  anarchy,  partly  because 
it  was  likely  to  be  confused  with  and  to  prejudice,  as  in  fact 
it  did,  the  Reformation  movement,  partly  because  (as  he 
thought)  it  degraded  the  Gospel  by  turning  a  spiritual  mes- 
sage into  a  program  of  social  reconstruction.  "This  article 
would  make  all  men  equal  and  so  change  the  spiritual  king- 
dom of  Christ  into  an  external  worldly  one  Impossible1  An 
earthly  kingdom  cannot  exist  without  inequality  of  persons 
Some  must  be  free,  others  serfs,  some  rulers,  others  subjects 
As  St.  Paul  says,  'Before  Christ  both  master  and  slave  are 
one.'  "  "9  After  nearly  four  centuries,  Luther's  apprehensions 
of  a  too  hasty  establishment  of  the  Kingdom  of  Heaven 
appear  somewhat  exaggerated 

A  society  may  perish  by  corruption  as  well  as  by  violence. 
Where  the  peasants  battered,  the  capitalists  mined,  and 
Luther,  whose  ideal  was  the  patriarchal  ethics  of  a  world 
which,  if  it  ever  existed,  was  visibly  breaking  up,  had  as 
little  mercy  for  the  slow  poison  of  commerce  and  finance  as 
for  the  bludgeon  of  revolt.  No  contrast  could  be  more  strik- 
ing than  that  between  his  social  theory  and  the  outlook  of 
Calvin.  Calvin,  with  all  his  rigor,  accepted  the  main  institu- 
tions of  a  commercial  civilization,  and  supplied  a  creed  to 
the  classes  which  were  to  dominate  the  future.  The  eyes  of 
Luther  were  on  the  past  He  saw  no  room  in  a  Christian 
society  for  those  middle  classes  whom  an  English  statesman 
once  described  as  the  natural  repersentatives  of  the  human 
race.  International  trade,  banking  and  credit,  capitalist  in- 
dustry, the  whole  complex  of  economic  forces,  which,  next 
to  his  own  revolution,  were  to  be  the  mightiest  solvent  of 
the  medieval  world,  seem  to  him  to  belong  in  their  very 
essence  to  the  kingdom  of  darkness  which  the  Christian  will 
shun.  He  attacks  the  authority  of  the  canon  law,  only  to 
reaffirm  more  dogmatically  the  detailed  rules  which  it  had 
been  used  to  enforce.  When  he  discusses  economic  questions 
at  length,  as  in  his  Long  Sermon  on  Usury  in  1520,  or  his 
tract  On  Trade  and  Usury  in  1524,  his  doctrines  are  drawn 
from  the  straitest  interpretation  of  ecclesiastical  jurispru- 
dence, unsoftened  by  the  qualifications  with  which  canonists 


LUTHER  85 

themselves  had  attempted  to  adapt  its  rigors  to  the  exigen- 
cies of  practical  life. 

In  the  matter  of  prices  he  merely  rehearses  traditional 
doctrines  "A  man  should  not  say,  'I  will  sell  my  wares  as 
dear  as  I  can  or  please/  but  'I  will  sell  my  wares  as  is  right 
and  proper.'  For  thy  selling  should  not  be  a  work  that  is 
within  thy  own  power  or  will,  without  all  law  and  limit,  as 
though  thou  wert  a  God,  bounden  to  no  one.  But  because 
thy  selling  is  a  work  that  thou  performest  to  thy  neighbor, 
it  should  be  restrained  within  such  law  and  conscience  that 
thou  mayest  practice  it  without  harm  or  injury  to  him."  40 
If  a  price  is  fixed  by  public  authority,  the  seller  must  keep 
to  it  If  it  is  not,  he  must  follow  the  price  of  common  esti- 
mation If  he  has  to  determine  it  himself,  he  must  consider 
the  income  needed  to  maintain  him  in  his  station  in  life,  his 
labor,  and  his  risk,  and  must  settle  it  accordingly  He  must 
not  take  advantage  of  scarcity  to  raise  it  He  must  not  cor- 
ner the  market.  He  must  not  deal  in  futures.  He  must  not 
sell  dearer  for  deferred  payments 

On  the  subject  of  usury,  Luther  goes  even  further  than 
the  orthodox  teaching.  He  denounces  the  concessions  to 
practical  necessities  made  by  the  canonists.  "The  greatest 
misfortune  of  the  German  nation  is  easily  the  traffic  in  in- 
terest .  .  The  devil  invented  it,  and  the  Pope,  by  giving 
his  sanction  to  it,  has  done  untold  evil  throughout  the 
world  "41  Not  content  with  insisting  that  .lending  ought  to 
be  free,  he  denounces  the  payment  of  interest  as  compen- 
sation for  loss  and  the  practice  of  investing  in  rent-charges, 
both  of  which  the  canon  law  in  his  day  allowed,  and  would 
refuse  usurers  the  sacrament,  absolution,  and  Christian  bur- 
ial With  such  a  code  of  ethics,  Luther  naturally  finds  the 
characteristic  developments  of  his  generation — the  luxury 
trade  with  the  East,  international  finance,  speculation  on  the 
exchanges,  combinations  and  monopolies — shocking  beyond 
measure  tk  Foreign  merchandise  which  brings  from  Calicut 
and  India  and  the  like  places  wares  such  as  precious  silver 
and  jewels  and  spices  .  .  and  drain  the  land  and  people 
of  their  money,  should  not  be  permitted.  ...  Of  combina- 
tions I  ought  really  to  say  much,  but  the  matter  is  endless 
and  bottomless,  full  of  mere  greed  and  wrong.  .  .  .  Who 
is  so  stupid  as  not  to  see  that  combinations  are  mere  out- 
right monopolies,  which  even  heathen  civil  laws — I  will  say 


86  THE   CONTINENTAL   REFORMERS 

nothing  of  divine  right  and  Christian  law — condemn  as  a 
plainly  harmful  thing  in  all  the  world?"  42 

So  resolute  an  enemy  of  license  might  have  been  expected 
to  be  the  champion  of  law.  It  might  have  been  supposed 
that  Luther,  with  his  hatred  of  the  economic  appetites,  would 
have  hailed  as  an  ally  the  restraints  by  which,  at  least  in 
theory,  those  appetites  had  been  controlled.  In  reality,  of 
course,  his  attitude  towards  the  mechanism  of  ecclesiastical 
jurisprudence  and  discipline  was  the  opposite  It  was  one, 
not  merely  of  indifference,  but  of  repugnance  The  prophet 
who  scourged  with  whips  the  cupidity  of  the  individual  chas- 
tised with  scorpions  the  restrictions  imposed  upon  it  by 
society;  the  apostle  of  an  ideal  ethic  of  Christian  love  turned 
a  shattering  dialectic  on  the  corporate  organization  of  the 
Christian  Church.  In  most  ages,  so  tragic  a  parody  of  hu- 
man hopes  are  human  institutions,  there  have  been  some 
who  have  loved  mankind,  while  hating  almost  everything 
that  men  have  done  or  made  Of  that  temper  Luther,  who 
lived  at  a  time  when  the  contrast  betwen  a  sublime  theory 
and  a  hideous  reality  had  long  been  intolerable,  is  the  su- 
preme example.  He  preaches  a  selfless  charity,  but  he  recoil^ 
with  horror  from  every  institution  by  which  an  attempt  had 
been  made  to  give  it  a  concrete  expression  He  reiterate^ 
the  content  of  medieval  economic  teaching  with  a  literalness 
rarely  to  be  found  in  the  thinkers  of  the  later  Middle  Ages, 
but  for  the  rules  and  ordinances  in  which  it  had  received  a 
positive,  if  sadly  imperfect,  expression,  he  has  little  but  ab- 
horrence. God  speaks  to  the  soul,  not  through  the  mediation 
of  the  priesthood  or  of  social  institutions  built  up  by  man 
but  solus  cum  solo,  as  a  voice  in  the  heart  and  in  the  heart 
alone.  Thus  the  bridges  between  the  worlds  of  spirit  and  of 
sense  are  broken,  and  the  soul  is  isolated  from  the  society 
of  men,  that  it  may  enter  into  communion  with  its  Maker 
The  grace  that  is  freely  bestowed  upon  it  mav  overflow  in 
its  social  relations;  but  those  relations  can  supply  no  par- 
ticle of  spirtual  nourishment  to  make  easier  the  reception  of 
grace.  L:ke  the  primeval  confusion  into  which  the  fallen 
Angel  plunged  on  his  fatal  mission,  they  are  a  chaos  of 
brute  matter,  a  wilderness  of  dry  bones,  a  desert  unsanctified 
and  incapable  of  contributing  to  sanctification.  "It  is  cer- 
tain that  absolutely  none  among  outward  things,  under  what- 
ever name  they  may  be  reckoned,  has  anv  influence  in  pro- 


LUTHER  87 

ducing  Christian  righteousness  or  liberty.  .  .  .  One  thing, 
and  one  alone,  is  necessary  for  life,  justification  and  Chris- 
tian liberty;  and  that  is  the  most  holy  word  of  God,  the 
Gospel  of  Christ."  43 

The  difference  between  loving  men  as  a  result  of  first  lov- 
ing God,  and  learning  to  love  God  through  a  growing  love 
for  men,  may  not,  at  first  sight,  appear  profound  To  Luther 
it  seemed  an  abyss,  and  Luther  was  right  It  was,  in  a  sense, 
nothing  less  than  the  Reformation  itself  For  carried,  as  it 
was  not  carried  by  Luther,  to  its  logical  result,  the  argument 
made,  not  only  good  works,  but  sacraments  and  the  Church 
itself  unnecessary  The  question  of  the  religious  significance 
of  that  change  of  emphasis,  and  of  the  validity  of  the  intel- 
lectual processes  by  which  Luther  reached  his  conclusions,  is 
one  for  theologians  Its  effects  on  social  theory  were  stag- 
gering Since  salvation  is  bestowed  by  the  operation  of  grace 
in  the  heart  and  by  that  alone,  the  whole  fabric  of  organized 
religion,  which  had  mediated  between  the  individual  soul  and 
its  Maker — divinely  commissioned  hierarchy,  systematized 
activities,  corporate  institutions — drops  away,  as  the  blas- 
phemous trivialities  of  a  religion  of  works  The  medieval 
conception  of  the  social  order,  which  had  regarded  it  as  a 
highly  articulated  organism  of  members  contributing  in  their 
different  degrees  to  a  spiritual  purpose,  was  shattered,  and 
differences  which  had  been  distinctions  within  a  larger  unity 
were  now  set  in  irreconcilable  antagonism  to  each  other. 
Grace  no  longer  completed  nature  it  was  the  antithesis  of 
it  Man's  actions  as  a  member  of  society  were  no  longer  the 
extension  of  his  life  as  a  child  of  God  they  were  its  nega- 
tion Secular  interests  ceased  to  possess,  even  remotely,  a 
religious  significance,  they  might  compete  with  religion,  but 
they  could  not  enrich  it  Detailed  rules  of  conduct — a  Chris- 
tian casuistry — are  needless  or  objectionable  the  Christian 
has  a  sufficient  guide  in  the  Bible  and  in  his  own  conscience. 
In  one  sense,  the  distinction  between  the  secular  and  the 
religious  life  vanished.  Monasticism  was,  so  to  speak,  secu- 
larized, all  men  stood  henceforward  on  the  same  footing 
towards  God;  and  that  advance,  which  contained  the  germ 
of  all  subsequent  revolutions,  was  so  enormous  that  all  else 
seems  insignificant.  In  another  sense,  th~  distinction  became 
more  profound  than  ever  before.  For,  though  all  might  be 
sanctified,  it  was  their  inner  life  alone  which  could  partake 


88  THE    CONTINENTAL   REFORMERS 

of  sanctification.  The  world  was  divided  into  good  and  evil, 
light  and  darkness,  spirit  and  matter.  The  division  between 
them  was  absolute;  no  human  effort  could  span  the  chasm. 

The  remoter  corollaries  of  the  change  remained  to  be 
stated  by  subsequent  generations.  Luther  himself  was  not 
consistent.  He  believed  that  it  was  possible  to  maintain  the 
content  of  medieval  social  teaching,  while  rejecting  its  sanc- 
tions, and  he  insisted  that  good  works  would  be  the  fruit 
of  salvation  as  vehemently  as  he  denied  that  they  could 
contribute  to  its  attainment.  In  his  writings  on  social  ques- 
tions emphasis  on  the  traditional  Christian  morality  is  com- 
bined with  a  repudiation  of  its  visible  and  institutional 
framework,  and  in  the  tragic  struggle  which  results  between 
spirit  and  letter,  form  and  matter,  grace  and  works,  his  in- 
tention, at  least,  is  not  to  jettison  the  rules  of  good  con- 
science in  economic  matters,  but  to  purify  them  by  an 
immense  effort  of  simplification.  His  denunciation  of  medie- 
val charity,  fraternities,  mendicant  orders,  festivals  and 
pilgrimages,  while  it  drew  its  point  from  practical  abuses, 
sprang  inevitably  from  his  repudiation  of  the  idea  that  merit 
could  be  acquired  by  the  operation  of  some  special  machin- 
ery beyond  the  conscientious  discharge  of  the  ordinary  du- 
ties of  daily  life  His  demand  for  the  abolition  of  the  canon 
law  was  the  natural  corollary  of  his  belief  that  the  Bible 
was  an  all-sufficient  guide  to  action.  While  not  rejecting 
ecclesiastical  discipline  altogether,  he  is  impatient  of  it. 
The  Christian,  he  argues,  needs  no  elaborate  mechanism  to 
teach  him  his  duty  or  to  correct  him  if  he  neglects  it.  He 
has  the  Scriptures  and  his  own  conscience;  let  him  listen 
to  them.  "There  can  be  no  better  instructions  in  ...  all 
transactions  in  temporal  goods  than  that  every  man  who  is 
to  deal  with  his  neighbor  present  to  himself  these  command- 
ments: 'What  ye  would  that  others  should  do  unto  you,  do 
ye  also  unto  them,'  and  'Love  thy  neighbor  as  thyself.'  If 
these  were  followed  out,  then  everything  would  instruct 
and  arrange  itself;  then  no  law  books  nor  courts  nor  judi- 
cial actions  would  be  required;  all  things  would  quietly  and 
simply  be  set  to  rights,  for  every  one's  heart  and  conscience 
would  guide  him."  44 

"Everything  would  arrange  itself."  Few  would  deny  it. 
But  how  if  it  does  not?  Is  emotion  really  an  adequate  sub- 
stitute for  reason,  and  rhetoric  for  law?  Is  it  possible  to 


LUTHER  89 

solve  the  problem  which  social  duties  present  to  the  individ- 
ual by  informing  him  that  no  problem  exists?  If  it  is  true 
that  the  inner  life  is  the  sphere  of  religion,  does  it  neces- 
sarily follow  that  the  external  order  is  simply  irrelevant  to 
it?  To  wave  aside  the  world  of  institutions  and  law  as  alien 
to  that  of  the  spirit — is  not  this  to  abandon,  instead  of 
facing,  the  task  of  making  Christian  morality  prevail,  for 
which  medieval  writers,  with  their  conception  of  a  hierarchy 
of  values  related  to  a  common  end,  had  attempted,  however 
inadequately,  to  discover  a  formula?  A  Catholic  rationalist 
had  answered  by  anticipation  Luther's  contemptuous  dis- 
missal of  law  and  learning,  when  he  urged  that  it  was  use- 
less for  the  Church  to  prohibit  extortion,  unless  it  was 
prepared  to  undertake  the  intellectual  labor  of  defining  the 
transactions  to  which  the  prohibition  applied.4"'  It  was  a 
pity  that  Pecock's  douche  of  common  sense  was  not  of  a 
kind  which  could  be  appreciated  by  Luther.  He  denounced 
covetousness  in  general  terms,  with  a  surprising  exuberance 
of  invective  But,  confronted  with  a  request  for  advice  on 
the  specific  question  whether  the  authorities  of  Danzig 
shall  put  down  usury,  he  retreats  into  the  clouds.  "The 
preacher  shall  preach  only  the  Gospel  rule,  and  leave  it  to 
each  man  to  follow  his  own  conscience.  Let  him  who  can 
receive  it,  receive  it,  he  cannot  be  compelled  thereto  further 
than  the  Gospel  leads  willing  hearts  whom  the  spirit  of 
God  urges  forward/' 4(> 

Luther's  impotence  was  not  accidental  It  sprang  directly 
from  his  fundamental  conception  that  to  externalize  religion 
in  rules  and  ordinances  is  to  degrade  it.  He  attacked  the 
casuistry  of  the  canonists,  and  the  points  in  their  teaching 
with  regard  to  which  his  criticism  was  justified  were  only 
too  numerous  But  the  remedy  for  bad  law  is  good  law,  not 
lawlessness;  and  casuistry  is  merely  the  application  of  gen- 
eral principles  to  particular  cases,  which  is  involved  in  any 
living  system  of  jurisprudence,  whether  ecclesiastical  or 
secular.  If  the  principles  are  not  to  be  applied,  on  the 
ground  that  they  are  too  sublime  to  be  soiled  by  contact 
with  the  gross  woild  of  business  and  politics,  what  remains 
of  them?  Denunciations  such  as  Luther  launched  against 
the  Fuggers  and  the  peasants,  aspirations  for  an  idyll  of 
Christian  charity  and  simplicity,  such  as  he  advanced  in  his 


90  THE    CONTINENTAL   REFORMERS 

tract  On  Trade  and  Usury.  Pious  rhetoric  may  be  edifying, 
but  it  is  hardly  the  panoply  recommended  by  St.  Paul. 

"As  the  soul  needs  the  word  alone  for  life  and  justifica- 
tion, so  it  is  justified  by  faith  alone,  and  not  by  any  works. 
.  .  .  Therefore  the  first  care  of  every  Christian  ought  to  be 
to  lay  aside  all  reliance  on  works,  and  to  strengthen  his 
faith  alone  more  and  more."47  The  logic  of  Luther's  re- 
ligious premises  was  more  potent  for  posterity  than  his  at- 
tachment to  the  social  ethics  of  the  past,  and  evolved  its 
own  inexorable  conclusions  in  spite  of  them.  It  enormously 
deepened  spiritual  experience,  and  sowed  the  seeds  from 
which  new  freedoms,  abhorrent  to  Luther,  were  to  spring. 
But  it  riveted  on  the  social  thought  of  Protestantism  a  dual- 
ism which,  as  its  implications  were  developed,  emptied  re- 
ligion of  its  social  content,  and  society  of  its  soul.  Between 
light  and  darkness  a  great  gulf  was  fixed.  Unable  to  climb 
upwards  plane  by  plane,  man  must  choose  between  salvation 
and  damnation.  If  he  despairs  of  attaining  the  austere 
heights  where  alone  true  faith  is  found,  no  human  institu- 
tion can  avail  to  help  him.  Such,  Luther  thinks,  will  be 
the  fate  of  only  too  many. 

He  himself  was  conscious  that  he  had  left  the  world  of 
secular  activities  perilously  divorced  from  spiritual  re- 
straints. He  met  the  difficulty,  partly  with  an  admission 
that  it  was  insuperable,  as  one  who  should  exult  in  the 
majestic  unreasonableness  of  a  mysterious  Providence,  whose 
decrees  might  not  be  broken,  but  could  not,  save  by  a  few, 
be  obeyed ;  partly  with  an  appeal  to  the  State  to  occupy  the 
province  of  social  ethics,  for  which  his  philosophy  could  find 
no  room  in  the  Church.  "Here  it  will  be  asked,  'Who  then 
can  be  saved,  and  where  shall  we  find  Christians?  For  in 
this  fashion  no  merchandising  would  remain  on  earth.'  .  .  . 
You  see  it  as  I  said,  that  Christians  are  rare  people  on 
earth.  Therefore  stern  hard  civil  rule  is  necessary  in  the 
world,  lest  the  world  become  wild,  peace  vanish,  and  com- 
merce and  common  interests  be  destroyed.  ...  No  one  need 
think  that  the  world  can  be  ruled  without  blood.  The  civil 
sword  shall  and  must  be  red  and  bloody."  48 

Thus  the  axe  takes  the  place  of  the  stake,  and  authority, 
expelled  from  the  altar,  finds  a  new  and  securer  home  upon 
the  throne.  The  maintenance  of  Christian  morality  is  to  be 
transferred  from  the  discredited  ecclesiastical  authorities  to 


CALVIN  91 

the  hands  of  the  State.  Skeptical  as  to  the  existence  of 
unicorns  and  salamanders,  the  age  of  Machiavelli  and  Henry 
VIII  found  food  for  its  credulity  in  the  worship  of  that 
rare  monster,  the  God-fearing  Prince. 

III.    CALVIN 

The  most  characteristic  and  influential  form  of  Protes- 
tantism in  the  two  centuries  following  the  Reformation  is 
that  which  descends,  by  one  path  or  another,  from  the 
teaching  of  Calvin.  Unlike  the  Lutheranism  from  which  it 
sprang,  Calvinism,  assuming  different  shapes  in  different 
countries,  became  an  international  movement,  which  brought, 
not  peace,  but  a  sword,  and  the  path  of  which  was  strewn 
with  revolutions.  Where  Lutheranism  had  been  socially  con- 
servative, deferential  to  established  political  authorities,  the 
exponent  of  a  personal,  almost  a  quietistic,  piety,  Calvinism 
was  an  active  and  radical  force.  It  was  a  creed  which  sought, 
not  merely  to  purify  the  individual,  but  to  reconstruct 
Church  and  State,  and  to  renew  society  by  penetrating  every 
department  of  life,  public  as  well  as  private,  with  the  influ- 
ence of  religion. 

Upon  the  immense  political  reactions  of  Calvinism,  this  is 
not  the  place  to  enlarge.  As  a  way  of  life  and  a  theory  of  so- 
ciety, it  possessed  from  the  beginning  one  characteristic 
which  was  both  novel  and  important.  It  assumed  an  eco- 
nomic organization  which  was  relatively  advanced,  and  ex- 
pounded its  social  ethics  on  the  basis  of  it.  In  this  respect 
the  teaching  of  the  Puritan  moralists  who  derive  most  direct- 
ly from  Calvin  is  in  marked  contrast  with  that  both  of  me- 
dieval theologians  and  of  Luther.  The  difference  is  not  merely 
one  of  the  conclusions  reached,  but  of  the  plane  on  which  the 
discussion  is  conducted.  The  background,  not  only  of  most 
medieval  theory,  but  also  of  Luther  and  his  English  contem- 
poraries, is  the  traditional  stratification  of  rural  society.  It 
is  a  natural,  rather  than  a  money,  economy,  consisting  of  the 
petty  dealings  of  peasants  and  craftsmen  in  the  small  market 
town,  where  industry  is  carried  on  for  the  subsistence  of  the 
household  and  the  consumption  of  wealth  follows  hard  upon 
the  production  of  it,  and  where  commerce  and  finance  are 
occasional  incidents,  rather  than  the  forces  which  keep  the 
whole  svstem  in  motion.  When  they  criticize  economic  abuses, 


92  THE    CONTINENTAL   REFORMERS 

it  is  precisely  against  departures  from  that  natural  state  of 
things — against  the  enterprise,  the  greed  of  gain,  the  restless 
competition,  which  disturb  the  stability  of  the  existing  order 
with  clamorous  economic  appetites — that  their  criticism  is 
directed. 

These  ideas  were  the  traditional  retort  to  the  evils  of  un- 
scrupulous commercialism,  and  they  left  some  trace  on  the 
writings  of  the  Swiss  reformers.  Zwingli,  for  example,  who, 
in  his  outlook  on  society,  stood  midway  between  Luther  and 
Calvin,  insists  on  the  oft-repeated  thesis  that  private  prop- 
erty originates  in  sin,  warns  the  rich  that  they  can  hardly 
enter  the  Kingdom  of  Heaven;  denounces  the  Councils  of 
Constance  and  Basel — "assembled,  forsooth,  at  the  bidding 
of  the  Holy  Ghost'' — for  showing  indulgence  to  the  mort- 
gaging of  land  on  the  security  of  crops;  and,  while  empha- 
sizing that  interest  must  be  paid  when  the  State  sanctions  it, 
condemns  it  in  itself  as  contrary  to  the  law  of  God  '"  Of  the 
attempts  made  at  Zurich  and  Geneva  to  repress  extortion 
something  is  said  below.  But  these  full-blooded  denuncia- 
tions of  capitalism  were  not  intended  by  their  authors  to  sup- 
ply a  rule  of  practical  life,  since  it  was  the  duty  of  the  in- 
dividual to  comply  with  the  secular  legislation  by  which 
interest  was  permitted,  and  already,  when  they  were  uttered, 
they  had  ceased  to  represent  the  conclusion  of  the  left  wing 
of  the  Reformed  Churches. 

For  Calvin,  and  still  more  his  later  interpreters,  began 
their  voyage  lower  down  the  stream.  Unlike  Luther,  who  saw 
economic  life  with  the  eyes  of  a  peasant  and  a  mystic,  they 
approached  it  as  men  of  affairs,  disposed  neither  to  idealize 
the  patriarchal  virtues  of  the  peasant  community,  nor  to 
regard  with  suspicion  the  mere  fact  of  capitalist  enter- 
prise in  commerce  and  finance.  Like  early  Christianity  and 
modern  socialism,  Calvinism  was  largely  an  urban  move- 
ment; like  them,  in  its  earlier  days,  it  was  carried  from  coun- 
try to  country  partly  by  emigrant  traders  and  workmen ;  and 
its  stronghold  was  precisely  in  those  social  groups  to  which 
the  traditional  scheme  of  social  ethics,  with  its  tieatment  of 
economic  interests  as  a  quite  minor  aspect  of  human  affairs, 
must  have  seemed  irrelevant  or  artificial.  As  was  to  be  ex- 
pected in  the  exponents  of  a  faith  which  had  its  headquarters 
at  Geneva,  and  later  its  most  influential  adherents  in  great 
business  centers,  like  Antwerp  with  its  industrial  hinterland, 


CALVIN  93 

London,  and  Amsterdam,  its  leaders  addressed  their  teach- 
ing, not  of  course  exclusively,  but  none  the  less  primarily, 
to  the  classes  engaged  in  trade  and  industry,  who  formed 
the  most  modern  and  progressive  elements  in  the  life  of  the 
age. 

In  doing  so  they  naturally  started  from  a  frank  recogni- 
tion of  the  necessity  of  capital,  credit  and  banking,  large- 
scale  commerce  and  finance,  and  the  other  practical  facts  of 
business  life.  They  thus  broke  with  the  tradition  which,  re- 
garding a  preoccupation  with  economic  interests  "beyond 
what  is  necessary  for  subsistence"  as  reprehensible,  had  stig- 
matized the  middleman  as  a  parasite  and  the  usurer  as  a 
thief.  They  set  the  profits  of  trade  and  finance,  which  to  the 
medieval  writer,  as  te  Luther,  only  with  difficulty  escaped 
censure  as  turpe  lucrum,  on  the  same  level  of  respectability 
as  the  earnings  of  the  laborer  and  the  rents  of  the  landlord. 
"What  reason  is  there,"  wrote  Calvin  to  a  correspondent, 
"why  the  income  from  business  should  not  be  larger  than 
that  from  land-owning?  Whence  do  the  merchant's  profits 
come,  except  from  his  own  diligence  and  industry?"  50  It  was 
quite  in  accordance  with  the  spirit  of  those  words  that  Bu- 
cer,  even  while  denouncing  the  frauds  and  avarice  of  mer- 
chants, should  urge  the  English  Government  to  undertake 
the  development  of  the  woollen  industry  on  mercantilist 
lines.51 

Since  it  is  the  environment  of  the  industrial  and  commer- 
cial classes  which  is  foremost  in  the  thoughts  of  Calvin  and 
his  followers,  they  have  to  make  terms  with  its  practical  ne- 
cessities. It  is  not  that  they  abandon  the  claim  of  religion  to 
moralize  economic  life,  but  that  the  life  which  they  are  con- 
cerned to  moralize  is  one  in  which  the  main  features  of  a 
commercial  civilization  are  taken  for  granted,  and  that  it  is 
for  application  to  such  conditions  that  their  teaching  is  de- 
signed. Early  Calvinism,  as  we  shall  see,  has  its  own  rule, 
and  a  rigorous  rule,  for  the  conduct  of  economic  affairs.  But 
it  no  longer  suspects  the  whole  world  of  economic  motives  as 
alien  to  the  life  of  the  spirit,  or  distrusts  the  capitalist  as  one 
who  has  necessarily  grown  rich  on  the  misfortunes  of  his 
neighbor,  or  regards  poverty  as  in  itself  meritorious,  and  it 
is  perhaps  the  first  systematic  body  of  religious  teaching 
which  can  be  said  to  recognize  and  applaud  the  economic 
virtues.  Its  enemy  is  not  the  accumulation  of  riches,  but  their 


94  THE   CONTINENTAL   REFORMERS 

misuse  for  purposes  of  self-indulgence  or  ostentation.  Its 
ideal  is  a  society  which  seeks  wealth  with  the  sober  gravity 
of  men  who  are  conscious  at  once  of  disciplining  their  own 
characters  by  patient  labor,  and  of  devoting  themselves  to  a 
service  acceptable  to  God. 

It  is  in  the  light  of  that  change  of  social  perspective  that 
the  doctrine  of  usury  associated  with  the  name  of  Calvin  is 
to  be  interpreted.  Its  significance  consisted,  not  in  the  phase 
which  it  marked  in  the  technique  of  economic  analysis,  but 
in  its  admission  to  a  new  position  of  respectability  of  a  pow- 
erful and  growing  body  of  social  interests,  which,  however 
irrepressible  in  practice,  had  hitherto  been  regarded  by  reli- 
gious theory  as,  at  best,  of  dubious  propriety,  and,  at  worst, 
as  frankly  immoral.  Strictly  construed,  the  famous  pro- 
nouncement strikes  the  modern  reader  rather  by  its  rigor 
than  by  its  indulgence.  "Calvin,"  wrote  an  English  divine  a 
generation  after  his  death,  "deals  with  usurie  as  the  apothe- 
carie  doth  with  poyson."  52  The  apologetic  was  just,  for  nei- 
ther his  letter  to  Occolampadius,  nor  his  sermon  on  the  same 
subject,  reveal  any  excessive  tolerance  for  the  trade  of  the 
financier.  That  interest  is  lawful,  provided  that  it  does  not 
exceed  an  official  maximum,  that,  even  when  a  maximum  is 
fixed,  loans  must  be  made  gratis  to  the  poor,  that  the  bor- 
rower must  reap  as  much  advantage  as  the  lender,  that  ex- 
cessive security  must  not  be  exacted,  that  what  is  venial  as 
an  occasional  expedient  is  reprehensible  when  carried  on  as 
a  regular  occupation,  that  no  man  may  snatch  economic  gain 
for  himself  to  the  injury  of  his  neighbor — a  condonation  of 
usury  protected  by  such  embarrassing  entanglements  can 
have  offered  but  tepid  consolation  to  the  devout  money- 
lender. 

Contemporaries  interpreted  Calvin  to  mean  that  the  debtor 
might  properly  be  asked  to  concede  some  small  part  of  his 
profits  to  the  creditor  with  whose  capital  they  had  been 
earned,  but  that  the  exaction  of  interest  was  wrong  if  it 
meant  that  "the  creditor  becomes  rich  by  the  sweat  of  the 
debtor,  and  the  debtor  does  not  reap  the  reward  of  his  labor." 
There  have  been  ages  in  which  such  doctrines  would  have 
been  regarded  as  an  attack  on  financial  enterprise  rather  than 
.as  a  defense  of  it.  Nor  were  Calvin's  specific  contributions 
to  the  theory  of  usury  strikingly  original.  As  a  hard-headed 
lawyer,  he  was  free  both  from  the  incoherence  and  from  the 


CALVIN  95 

idealism  of  Luther,  and  his  doctrine  was  probably  regarded 
by  himself  merely  as  one  additional  step  in  the  long  series  of 
developments  through  which  ecclesiastical  jurisprudence  on 
the  subject  had  already  gone.  In  emphasizing  the  difference 
between  the  interest  wrung  from  the  necessities  of  the  poor 
and  the  interest  which  a  prosperous  merchant  could  earn  with 
borrowed  capital,  he  had  been  anticipated  by  Major;  in  his 
sanction  of  a  moderate  rate  on  loans  to  the  rich,  his  position 
was  the  same  as  that  already  assumed,  though  with  some 
hesitation,  by  Melanchthon.  The  picture  of  Calvin,  the  or- 
ganizer and  disciplinarian,  as  the  parent  of  laxity  in  social 
ethics,  is  a  legend,  Like  the  author  of  another  revolution  in 
economic  theory,  he  might  have  turned  on  his  popularizers 
with  the  protest:  "I  am  not  a  Calvinist." 

Legends  are  apt,  however,  to  be  as  right  in  substance  as 
they  are  wrong  in  detail,  and  both  its  critics  and  its  defend- 
ers were  correct  in  regarding  Calvin's  treatment  of  capital  as 
a  watershed.  What  he  did  was  to  change  the  plane  on  which 
the  discussion  was  conducted,  by  treating  the  ethics  of  mon- 
ey-lending, not  as  a  matter  to  be  decided  by  an  appeal  to  a 
special  body  of  doctrine  on  the  subject  of  usury,  but  as  a 
particular  case  of  the  general  problem  of  the  social  relations 
of  a  Christian  community,  which  must  be  solved  in  the  light 
of  existing  circumstances.  The  significant  feature  in  his  dis- 
cussion of  the  subject  is  that  he  assumes  credit  to  be  a  nor- 
mal and  inevitable  incident  in  the  life  of  society.  He  there- 
fore dismisses  the  oft-quoted  passages  from  the  Old  Testa- 
ment and  the  Fathers  as  irrelevant,  because  designed  for 
conditions  which  no  longer  exist,  argues  that  the  payment 
of  interest  for  capital  is  as  reasonable  as  the  payment  of  rent 
for  land,  and  throws  on  the  conscience  of  the  individual  the 
obligation  of  seeing  that  it  does  not  exceed  the  amount  dic- 
tated by  natural  justice  and  the  golden  rule.  He  makes,  in 
short,  a  fresh  start,  argues  that  what  is  permanent  is,  not  the 
rule  "non  joenerabis"  but  "riquiti  et  la  droiture,"  and  ap- 
peals from  Christian  tradition  to  commercial  common  sense, 
which  he  is  sanguine  enough  to  hope  will  be  Christian.  Chi 
such  a  view  all  extortion  is  to  be  avoided  by  Christians.  But 
capital  and  credit  are  indispensable;  the  financier  is  not  a 
pariah,  but  a  useful  member  of  society;  and  lending  at  in- 
terest, provided  that  the  rate  is  reasonable  and  that  loans 
are  made  freely  to  the  poor,  is  not  per  se  more  extortionate 


96  THE   CONTINENTAL   REFORMERS 

than  any  other  of  the  economic  transactions  without  which 
human  affairs  cannot  be  carried  on.  That  acceptance  of  the 
realities  of  commercial  practice  as  a  starting-point  was  of 
momentous  importance.  It  meant  that  Calvinism  and  its  off- 
shoots took  their  stand  on  the  side  of  the  activities  which 
were  to  be  most  characteristic  of  the  future,  and  insisted  that 
it  was  not  by  renouncing  them,  but  by  untiring  concentra- 
tion on  the  task  of  using  for  the  glory  of  God  the  opportuni- 
ties which  they  offered,  that  the  Christian  life  could  and 
must  be  lived. 

It  was  on  this  practical  basis  of  urban  industry  and  com- 
mercial enterprise  that  the  structure  of  Calvinistic  social 
ethics  was  erected.  Upon  their  theological  background  it 
would  be  audacious  to  enter.  But  even  an  amateur  may  be 
pardoned,  if  he  feels  that  there  have  been  few  systems  in 
which  the  practical  conclusions  flow  by  so  inevitable  a  logic 
from  the  theological  premises.  "God  not  only  foresaw,"  Cal- 
vin wrote,  "the  fall  of  the  first  man,  ...  but  also  arranged 
all  by  the  determination  of  his  own  will."  r>R  Certain  individ- 
uals he  chose  as  his  elect,  predestined  to  salvation  from  eter- 
nity by  "his  gratuitous  mercy,  totally  irrespective  of  human 
merit";  the  remainder  have  been  consigned  to  eternal  dam- 
nation, "by  a  just  and  irreprehensible,  but  incomprehensible, 
judgment."  54  Deliverance,  in  short,  is  the  work,  not  of  man 
himself,  who  can  contribute  nothing  to  it,  but  of  an  objective 
Power.  Human  effort,  social  institutions,  the  world  of  cul- 
ture, are  at  best  irrelevant  to  salvation,  and  at  worst  mis- 
chievous. They  distract  man  from  the  true  aim  of  his  exist- 
ence and  encourage  reliance  upon  broken  reeds. 

That  aim  is  not  personal  salvation,  but  the  glorification  of 
God,  to  be  sought,  not  by  prayer  only,  but  by  action — the 
sanctification  of  the  world  by  strife  and  labor.  For  Calvinism, 
with  all  its  repudiation  of  personal  merit,  is  intensely  practi- 
cal. Good  works  are  not  a  way  of  attaining  salvation,  but 
they  are  indispensable  as  a  proof  that  salvation  has  been  at- 
tained. The  central  paradox  of  religious  ethics — that  only 
those  are  nerved  with  the  courage  needed  to  turn  the  world 
upside  down,  who  are  convinced  that  already,  in  a  higher 
sense,  it  is  disposed  for  the  best  by  a  Power  of  which  they 
are  the  humble  instruments— finds  in  it  a  special  exemplifi- 
cation. For  the  Calvinist  the  world  is  ordained  to  show  forth 
the  majesty  of  God,  and  the  duty  of  the  Christian  is  to  live 


CALVIN  97 

for  that  end.  His  task  is  at  once  to  discipline  his  individual 
life,  and  to  create  a  sanctified  society.  The  Church,  the  State, 
the  community  in  which  he  lives,  must  not  merely  be  a  means 
of  personal  salvation,  or  minister  to  his  temporal  needs.  It 
must  be  a  "Kingdom  of  Christ,"  in  which  individual  duties 
are  performed  by  men  conscious  that  they  are  "ever  in  their 
great  Taskmaster's  eye,"  and  the  whole  fabric  is  preserved 
from  corruption  by  a  stringent  and  all-embracing  discipline. 
The  impetus  to  reform  or  revolution  springs  in  every  age 
from  the  realization  of  the  contrast  between  the  external  or- 
der of  society  and  the  moral  standards  recognized  as  valid  by 
the  conscience  or  reason  of  the  individual.  And  naturally  it 
is  in  periods  of  swift  material  progress,  such  as  the  sixteenth 
and  eighteenth  centuries,  that  such  a  contrast  is  most  acutely 
felt.  The  men  who  made  the  Reformation  had  seen  the  Mid- 
dle Ages  close  in  the  golden  autumn  which,  amid  all  the  cor- 
ruption and  tyranny  of  the  time,  still  glows  in  the  pictures 
of  Nurnberg  and  Frankfurt  drawn  by  Aeneas  Silvius  and  in 
the  woodcuts  of  Durer  And  already  a  new  dawn  of  economic 
prosperity  was  unfolding.  Its  promise  was  splendid,  but  it 
had  been  accompanied  by  a  cynical  materialism  which 
seemed  a  denial  of  all  that  had  been  meant  by  the  Christian 
virtues,  and  which  was  the  more  horrifying  because  it  was 
in  the  capital  of  the  Christian  Church  that  it  reached  its 
height.  Shocked  by  the  gulf  between  theory  and  practice,  men 
turned  this  way  and  that  to  find  some  solution  of  the  ten- 
sion which  racked  them.  The  German  reformers  followed 
one  road  and  preached  a  return  to  primitive  simplicity.  But 
who  could  obliterate  the  achievements  of  two  centuries,  or 
blot  out  the  new  worlds  which  science  had  revealed?  The  Hu- 
manists took  another,  which  should  lead  to  the  gradual  re- 
generation of  mankind  by  the  victory  of  reason  over  super- 
stition and  brutality  and  avarice.  But  who  could  wait  for  so 
distant  a  consummation?  Might  there  not  be  a  third?  Was 
it  not  possible  that,  purified  and  disciplined,  the  very  quali- 
ties which  economic  success  demanded — thrift,  diligence,  so- 
briety, frugality — were  themsleves,  after  all,  the  foundation, 
at  least,  of  the  Christian  virtues?  Was  it  not  conceivable 
that  the  gulf  which  yawned  between  a  luxurious  world  and 
the  life  of  the  spirit  could  be  bridged,  not  by  eschewing  ma- 
terial interests  as  the  kingdom  of  darkness,  but  by  dedicat- 
ing them  to  the  service  of  God? 


98  THE   CONTINENTAL  REFORMERS 

It  was  that  revolution  in  the  traditional  scale  of  ethical 
values  which  the  Swiss  reformers  desired  to  achieve;  it  was 
that  new  type  of  Christian  character  that  they  labored  to 
create.  Not  as  part  of  any  scheme  of  social  reform,  but  as 
elements  in  a  plan  of  moral  regeneration,  they  seized  on  the 
aptitudes  cultivated  by  the  life  of  business  and  affairs, 
Stamped  on  them  a  new  sanctification,  and  used  them  as  the 
warp  of  a  society  in  which  a  more  than  Roman  discipline 
should  perpetuate  a  character  the  exact  antithesis  of  that  fos- 
tered by  obedience  to  Rome.  The  Roman  Church,  it  was 
held,  through  the  example  of  its  rulers,  had  encouraged  lux- 
ury and  ostentation;  the  members  of  the  Reformed  Church 
must  be  economical  and  modest.  It  had  sanctioned  the  spu- 
rious charity  of  indiscriminate  almsgiving;  the  true  Chris- 
tian must  repress  mendicancy  and  insist  on  the  virtues  of 
industry  and  thrift.  It  had  allowed  the  faithful  to  believe 
that  they  could  atone  for  a  life  of  worldliness  by  the  savor- 
less formality  of  individual  good  works  reduced  to  a  com- 
mercial system,  as  though  man  could  keep  a  profit  and  loss 
account  with  his  Creator:  the  true  Christian  must  organize 
his  life  as  a  whole  for  the  service  of  his  Master.  It  had  re- 
buked the  pursuit  of  gain  as  lower  than  the  life  of  religion, 
even  while  it  took  bribes  from  those  who  pursued  gain  with 
success:  the  Christian  must  conduct  his  business  with  a  high 
seriousness,  as  in  itself  a  kind  of  religion. 

Such  teaching,  whatever  its  theological  merits  or  defects, 
was  admirably  designed  to  liberate  economic  energies,  and  to 
weld  into  a  disciplined  social  force  the  rising  bourgeoisie, 
conscious  of  the  contrast  between  its  own  standards  and 
those  of  a  laxer  world,  proud  of  its  vocation  as  the  standard- 
bearer  of  the  economic  virtues,  and  determined  to  vindicate 
an  open  road  for  its  own  way  of  life  by  the  use  of  every 
weapon,  including  political  revolution  and  war,  because  the 
issue  which  was  at  stake  was  not  merely  convenience  or  self- 
interest,  but  the  will  of  God.  Calvinism  stood,  in  short,  not 
only  for  a  new  doctrine  of  theology  and  ecclesiastical  gov- 
ernment, but  for  a  new  scale  of  moral  values  and  a  new  ideal 
of  social  conduct.  Its  practical  message,  it  might  perhaps  be 
said,  was  la  carrier e  ouverte — not  aux  talents,  but  au 
caractere. 

Once  the  world  had  been  settled  to  their  liking,  the  middle 
classes  persuaded  themselves  that  they  were  the  convinced 


CALVIN  99 

enemies  of  violence  and  the  devotees  of  the  principle  of  or- 
der. While  their  victories  were  still  to  win,  they  were  every- 
where the  spear-head  of  revolution.  It  is  not  wholly  fanciful 
to  say  that,  on  a  narrower  stage  but  with  not  less  formidable 
weapons,  Calvin  did  for  the  bourgeoisie  of  the  sixteenth  cen- 
tury what  Marx  did  for  the  proletariat  of  the  nineteenth,  or 
that  the  doctrine  of  predestination  satisfied  the  same  hunger 
for  an  assurance  that  the  forces  of  the  universe  are  on  the 
side  of  the  elect  as  was  to  be  assuaged  in  a  different  age  by 
the  theory  of  historical  materialism.  He  set  their  virtues  at 
their  best  in  sharp  antithesis  with  the  vices  of  the  established 
order  at  its  worst,  taught  them  to  feel  that  they  were  a 
chosen  people,  made  them  conscious  of  their  great  destiny  in 
the  Providential  plan  and  resolute  to  realize  it.  The  new  law 
was  graven  on  tablets  of  flesh ;  it  not  merely  rehearsed  a  les- 
son, but  fashioned  a  soul.  Compared  with  the  quarrelsome, 
self-indulgent  nobility  of  most  European  countries,  or  with 
the  extravagant  and  half-bankrupt  monarchies,  the  middle 
classes,  in  whom  Calvinism  took  root  most  deeply,  were  a 
race  of  iron.  It  was  not  surprising  that  they  made  several 
revolutions,  and  imprinted  their  conceptions  of  political  and 
social  expediency  on  the  public  life  of  half  a  dozen  different 
States  in  the  Old  World  and  in  the  New 

The  two  main  elements  in  this  teaching  were  the  insistence 
on  personal  responsibility,  discipline  and  asceticism,  and  the 
call  to  fashion  for  the  Christian  character  an  objective  em- 
bodiment in  social  institutions  Though  logically  connected, 
they  were  often  in  practical  discord.  The  influence  of  Cal- 
vinism was  not  simple,  but  complex,  and  extended  far  be- 
yond the  circle  of  Churches  which  could  properly  be  called 
Calvinist.  Calvinist  theology  was  accepted  where  Calvinist 
discipline  was  repudiated.  The  bitter  struggle  between  Pres- 
byterians and  Independents  in  England  did  not  prevent  men, 
to  whom  the  whole  idea  of  religious  uniformity  was  funda- 
mantally  abhorrent,  from  drawing  inspiration  from  the  con- 
ception of  a  visible  Christian  society,  in  which,  as  one  of 
them  said,  the  Scripture  was  "  really  and  materially  to  be  ful- 
filled." G5  Both  an  intense  individualism  and  a  rigorous  Chris- 
tian Socialism  could  be  deduced  from  Calvin's  doctrine. 
Which  of  them  predominated  depended  on  differences  of  po- 
litical environment  and  of  social  class.  It  depended,  above 
allf  on  the  question  whether  Calvinists  were,  as  at  Geneva 


100  THE    CONTINENTAL  REFORMERS 

and  in  Scotland,  a  majority,  who  could  stamp  their  ideals 
on  the  social  order,  or,  as  in  England,  a  minority,  living  on 
the  defensive  beneath  the  suspicious  eyes  of  a  hostile  Gov- 
ernment. 

In  the  version  of  Calvinism  which  found  favor  with  the 
English  upper  classes  in  the  seventeenth  century,  individ- 
ualism in  social  affairs  was,  on  the  whole,  the  prevalent  phi- 
losophy. It  was  only  the  fanatic  and  the  agitator  who  drew 
inspiration  from  the  vision  of  a  New  Jerusalem  descending 
on  England's  green  and  pleasant  land,  and  the  troopers  of 
Fairfax  soon  taught  them  reason.  But,  if  the  theology  of 
Puritanism  was  that  of  Calvin,  its  conception  of  society,  di- 
luted by  the  practical  necessities  of  a  commercial  age,  and 
softened  to  suit  the  conventions  of  a  territorial  aristocracy, 
was  poles  apart  from  that  of  the  master  who  founded  a  dis- 
cipline, compared  with  which  that  of  Laud,  as  Laud  himself 
dryly  observed,56  was  a  thing  of  shreds  and  patches  As  both 
the  teaching  of  Calvin  himself,  and  the  practice  of  some 
Calvinist  communities,  suggest,  the  social  ethics  of  the  heroic 
age  of  Calvinism  savored  more  of  a  collectivist  dictatorship 
than  of  individualism.  The  expression  of  a  revolt  against  the 
medieval  ecclesiastical  system,  it  stood  itself,  where  circum- 
stances favored  it,  for  a  discipline  far  more  stringent  and 
comprehensive  than  that  of  the  Middle  Ages.  If,  as  some  his- 
torians have  argued,  the  philosophy  of  laissez  faire  emerged 
as  a  result  of  the  spread  of  Calvinism  among  the  middle 
classes,  it  did  so,  like  tolerance,  by  a  route  which  was  in- 
direct. It  was  accepted,  less  because  it  was  esteemed  for  its 
own  sake,  than  as  a  compromise  forced  upon  Calvinism  at  a 
comparatively  late  stage  in  its  history,  as  a  result  of  its  mod- 
ification by  the  pressure  of  commercial  interests,  or  of  a  bal- 
ance of  power  between  conflicting  authorities. 

The  spirit  of  the  system  is  suggested  by  its  treatment  of 
the  burning  question  of  Pauperism  The  reform  of  tradition- 
al methods  of  poor  relief  was  in  the  air — Vives  had  written 
his  celebrated  book  in  1526  " — and,  prompted  both  by  Hu- 
manists and  by  men  of  religion,  the  secular  authorities  all 
over  Europe  were  beginning  to  bestir  themselves  to  cope  with 
what  was,  at  best,  a  menace  to  social  order,  and,  at  worst,  a 
moral  scandal.  The  question  was  naturally  one  which  ap- 
pealed strongly  to  the  ethical  spirit  of  the  Reformation.  The 
characteristic  of  the  Swiss  reformers,  who  were  much  con- 


CALVIN  101 

cerned  with  it,  was  that  they  saw  the  situation  not,  like  the 
statesmen,  as  a  problem  of  police,  nor,  like  the  more  intelli- 
gent Humanists,  as  a  problem  of  social  organization,  but  as 
a  question  of  character.  Calvin  quoted  with  approval  the 
words  of  St.  Paul,  "If  a  man  will  not  work,  neither  shall  he 
eat,"  condemned  indiscriminate  alms-giving  as  vehemently 
as  any  Utilitarian,  and  urged  that  the  ecclesiastical  authori- 
ties should  regularly  visit  every  family  to  ascertain  whether 
its  members  were  idle,  or  drunken,  or  otherwise  undesirable.58 
Oecolampadius  wrote  two  tracts  on  the  relief  of  the  poor.59 
Bullinger  lamented  the  army  of  beggars  produced  by  monas- 
tic charity,  and  secured  part  of  the  emoluments  of  a  dissolved 
abbey  for  the  maintenance  of  a  school  for  the  assistance  of 
the  destitute.60  In  the  plan  for  the  reorganization  of  poor  re- 
lief at  Zurich,  which  was  drafted  by  Zwingli  in  1525,  all 
mendicancy  was  strictly  forbidden;  travellers  were  to  be  re- 
lieved on  condition  that  they  left  the  town  next  day;  provi- 
sion was  to  be  made  for  the  sick  and  aged  in  special  institu- 
tions; no  inhabitant  was  to  be  entitled  to  relief  who  wore 
ornaments  or  luxurious  clothes,  who  failed  to  attend  church, 
or  who  played  cards  or  was  otherwise  disreputable.  The  basis 
of  his  whole  scheme  was  the  duty  of  industry  and  the  danger 
of  relaxing  the  incentive  to  work.  "With  labor,"  he  wrote, 
uwill  no  man  now  support  himself  .  .  .  And  yet  labor  is  a 
thing  so  good  and  godlike  .  .  .  that  makes  the  body  hale  and 
strong  and  cures  the  sicknesses  produced  by  idleness.  .  .  . 
In  the  things  of  this  life,  the  laborer  is  most  like  to  God."  61 
In  the  assault  on  pauperism,  moral  and  economic  motives 
were  not  distinguished  The  idleness  of  the  mendicant  was 
both  a  sin  against  God  and  a  social  evil;  the  enterprise  of 
the  thriving  tradesman  was  at  once  a  Christian  virtue  and  a 
benefit  to  the  community.  The  same  combination  of  religious 
zeal  and  practical  shrewdness  prompted  the  attacks  on  gam- 
bling, swearing,  excess  in  apparel  and  self-indulgence  in  eat- 
ing and  drinking.  The  essence  of  the  system  was  not  preach- 
ing or  propaganda,  though  it  was  prolific  of  both,  but  the  at- 
tempt to  crystallize  a  moral  ideal  in  the  daily  life  of  a  visible 
society,  which  should  be  at  once  a  Church  and  a  State.  Hav- 
ing overthrown  monastlcism,  its  aim  was  to  turn  the  secular 
world  into  a  gigantic  monastery,  and  at  Geneva,  for  a  short 
time,  it  almost  succeeded.  "In  other  places,"  wrote  Knox  of 
that  devoted  city,  "I  confess  Christ  to  be  duly  preached,  but 


102  THE   CONTINENTAL   REFORMERS 

manners  and  religion  so  sincerely  reformed  I  have  not  yet 
seen  in  any  place  besides."  °2  Manners  and  morals  were  reg- 
ulated, because  it  is  through  the  minutiae  of  conduct  that  the 
enemy  of  mankind  finds  his  way  to  the  soul ;  the  traitors  to 
the  Kingdom  might  be  revealed  by  pointed  shoes  or  golden 
ear-rings,  as  in  1793  those  guilty  of  another  kind  of  incivisme 
were  betrayed  by  their  knee-breeches.  Regulation  meant  leg- 
islation, and,  still  more,  administration.  The  word  in  which 
both  were  summarized  was  Discipline. 

Discipline  Calvin  himself  described  as  the  nerves  of  re- 
ligion,0" and  the  common  observation  that  he  assigned  to  it 
the  same  primacy  as  Luther  had  given  to  faith  is  just.  As  or- 
ganized in  the  Calvinist  Churches,  it  was  designed  primarily 
to  safeguard  the  sacrament  and  to  enforce  a  censorship  of 
morals,  and  thus  differed  in  scope  and  purpose  from  the 
canon  law  of  the  Church  of  Rome,  as  the  rules  of  a  private 
society  may  differ  from  the  code  of  a  State.  Its  establishment 
at  Geneva,  in  the  form  which  it  assumed  in  the  last  half  of 
the  sixteenth  century,  was  the  result  of  nearly  twenty  years 
of  struggle  between  the  Council  of  the  city  and  the  Consis- 
tory, composed  of  ministers  and  laymen.  It  was  only  in  1555 
that  the  latter  finally  vindicated  its  right  to  excommunicate, 
and  only  in  the  edition  of  the  Institutes  which  appeared  in 
1559  that  a  scheme  of  church  organization  and  discipline 
was  set  out.  But,  while  the  answer  to  the  question  of  the 
constitution  of  the  authority  by  whom  discipline  was  to  be 
exercised  depended  on  political  conditions,  and  thus  differed 
in  different  places  and  periods,  the  necessity  of  enforcing  a 
rule  of  life,  which  was  the  practical  aspect  of  discipline,  was 
from  the  start  of  the  very  essence  of  Calvinism.  Its  impor- 
tance was  the  theme  of  a  characteristic  letter  addressed  by 
Calvin  to  Somerset  in  October  1548,  the  moment  of  social 
convulsion  for  which  Bucer  wrote  his  book,  De  Regno 
Christi.  The  Protector  is  reminded  that  it  is  not  from  lack  of 
preaching,  but  from  failure  to  enforce  compliance  with  it, 
that  the  troubles  of  England  have  sprung.  Though  crimes  of 
violence  are  punished,  the  licentious  are  spared,  and  the  li- 
centious have  no  part  in  the  Kingdom  of  God.  He  is  urged 
to  make  sure  that  "les  hommes  soient  tenus  en  bonne  et  hon- 
neste  discipline,"  and  to  be  careful  "que  ceulx  qui  oyent  la 
doctrine  de  TEvangile  s'approuvent  estre  Chrestiens  par 
sainctite  de  vie."  6* 


CALVIN  103 

"Prove  themselves  Christians  by  holiness  of  life" — the 
words  might  be  taken  as  the  motto  of  the  Swiss  reformers, 
and  their  projects  of  social  reconstruction  are  a  commentary 
on  the  sense  in  which  "holiness  of  life"  was  understood.  It 
was  in  that  spirit  that  Zwingli  took  the  initiative  in  forming 
at  Zurich  a  board  of  moral  discipline,  to  be  composed  of 
the  clergy,  the  magistrates  and  two  elders;  emphasized  the 
importance  of  excommunicating  offenders  against  Christian 
morals;  and  drew  up  a  list  of  sins  to  be  punished  by  excom- 
munication, which  included,  in  addition  to  murder  and  theft, 
unchastity,  perjury  and  avarice,  "especially  as  it  discovers 
itself  in  usury  and  fraud  "  ^  It  was  in  that  spirit  that  Calvin 
composed  in  the  Institutes  a  Protestant  Summa  and  manual 
of  moral  casuistry,  in  which  the  lightest  action  should  be 
brought  under  the  iron  control  of  a  universal  rule.  It  was  in 
that  spirit  that  he  drafted  the  heads  of  a  comprehensive 
scheme  of  municipal  government,  covering  the  whole  range 
of  civic  administration,  from  the  regulations  to  be  made  for 
markets,  crafts,  buildings  and  fairs  to  the  control  of  prices, 
interest  and  rents.66  It  was  in  that  spirit  that  he  made  Ge- 
neva a  city  of  glass,  in  which  every  household  lived  its  life 
under  the  supervision  of  a  spiritual  police,  and  that  for  a 
generation  Consistory  and  Council  worked  hand  in  hand,  the 
former  excommunicating  drunkards,  dancers  and  contemners 
of  religion,  the  latter  punishing  the  dissolute  with  fines  and 
imprisonment  and  the  heretic  with  death.  "Having  consid- 
ered," ran  the  preamble  to  the  ordinances  of  1576,  which 
mark  the  maturity  of  the  Genevese  Church,  "that  it  is  a 
thing  worthy  of  commendation  above  all  others,  that  the  doc- 
trine of  the  Holy  Gospel  of  our  Lord  Jesus  Christ  shall  be 
preserved  in  its  purity,  and  the  Christian  Church  duly  main- 
tained by  good  government  and  policy,  and  also  that  youth 
in  the  future  be  well  and  faithfully  instructed,  and  the  Hos- 
pital well  ordered  for  the  support  of  the  poor:  Which  things 
can  only  be  if  there  be  established  a  certain  rule  and  order 
of  living,  by  which  each  man  may  be  able  to  understand  the 
duties  of  his  position.  .  .  ."  °7  The  object  of  it  all  was  so  sim- 
ple. "Each  man  to  understand  the  duties  of  his  position"-— 
what  could  be  more  desirable,  at  Geneva  or  elsewhere?  It  is 
sad  to  reflect  that  the  attainment  of  so  laudable  an  end  in- 
volved the  systematic  use  of  torture,  the  beheading  of  a  child 
for  striking  its  parents,  and  the  burning  of  a  hundred  and 


104  THE    CONTINENTAL  REFORMERS 

fifty  heretics  in  sixty  years.68  Tantum  religio  potult  suadere 
malorum. 

Torturing  and  burning  were  practised  elsewhere  by  Gov- 
ernments which  affected  no  excessive  zeal  for  righteousness. 
The  characteristic  which  was  distinctive  of  Geneva — "the 
most  perfect  school  of  Christ  that  ever  was  on  earth  since 
the  days  of  the  Apostles"  G9 — was  not  its  merciless  intoler- 
ance, for  no  one  yet  dreamed  that  tolerance  was  possible.  It 
was  the  attempt  to  make  the  law  of  God  prevail  even  in  those 
matters  of  pecuniary  gain  and  loss  which  mankind,  to  judge 
by  its  history,  is  disposed  to  regard  more  seriously  than 
wounds  and  deaths.  "No  member  [of  the  Christian  body]," 
wrote  Calvin  in  his  Institutes,  "holds  his  gifts  to  himself,  or 
for  his  private  use,  but  shares  them  among  his  fellow  mem- 
bers, nor  does  he  derive  benefit  save  from  those  things  which 
proceed  from  the  common  profit  of  the  body  as  a  whole.  Thus 
the  pious  man  owes  to  his  brethren  all  that  it  is  in  his  power 
to  give."  70  It  was  natural  that  so  remorseless  an  attempt  to 
claim  the  totality  of  human  interests  for  religion  should  not 
hesitate  to  engage  even  the  economic  appetites,  before  which 
the  Churches  of  a  later  generation  were  to  lower  their  arms. 
If  Calvinism  welcomed  the  world  of  business  to  its  fold  with 
an  eagerness  unknown  before,  it  did  so  in  the  spirit  of  a  con- 
queror organizing  a  new  province,  not  of  a  suppliant  arrang- 
ing a  compromise  with  a  still  powerful  foe.  A  system  of  mor- 
als and  a  code  of  law  lay  ready  to  its  hand  in  the  Old  Testa- 
ment. Samuel  and  Agag,  King  of  the  Amalekites,  Jonah  and 
Nineveh,  Ahab  and  Naboth,  Elijah  and  the  prophets  of 
Baal,  Micaiah  the  son  of  Imlah,  the  only  true  prophet  of 
the  Lord,  and  Jeroboam  the  son  of  Nebat,  who  made  Israel 
to  sin,  worked  on  the  tense  imagination  of  the  Calvinist  as 
did  Brutus  and  Cassius  on  the  men  of  1793.  The  first  half- 
century  of  the  Reformed  Church  at  Geneva  saw  a  prolonged 
effort  to  organize  an  economic  order  worthy  of  the  Kingdom 
of  Christ,  in  which  the  ministers  played  the  part  of  Old  Tes- 
tament prophets  to  an  Israel  not  wholly  weaned  from  the 
fleshpots  of  Egypt. 

Apart  from  its  qualified  indulgence  to  interest,  Calvinism 
made  few  innovations  in  the  details  of  social  policy,  and  the 
contents  of  the  program  were  thoroughly  medieval.  The  nov- 
elty consisted  in  the  religious  zeal  which  was  thrown  into  its 
application.  The  organ  of  administration  before  which  of- 


CALVIN  105 

fenders  were  brought  was  the  Consistory,  a  mixed  body  Of 
laymen  and  ministers.  It  censures  harsh  creditors,  punishes 
usurers,  engrossers  and  monopolists,  reprimands  or  fines  the 
merchant  who  defrauds  his  clients,  the  clothmaker  whose 
stuff  is  an  inch  too  narrow,  the  dealer  who  provides  short 
measure  of  coal,  the  butcher  who  sells  meat  above  the  rates 
fixed  by  authority,  the  tailor  who  charges  strangers  excessive 
prices,  the  surgeon  who  demands  an  excessive  fee  for  an  op- 
eration 71  In  the  Consistory  the  ministers  appear  to  have 
carried  all  before  them,  and  they  are  constantly  pressing  for 
greater  stringency.  From  the  election  of  Beza  in  place  of  Cal- 
vin in  1564  to  his  death  in  1605,  hardly  a  year  passes  with- 
out a  new  demand  for  legislation  from  the  clergy,  a  new 
censure  on  economic  unrighteousness,  a  new  protest  against 
one  form  or  another  of  the  ancient  sin  of  avarice.  At  one  mo- 
ment, it  is  excessive  indulgence  to  debtors  which  rouses  their 
indignation;  at  another,  the  advance  of  prices  and  rents 
caused  by  the  influx  of  distressed  brethren  from  the  persecu- 
tions in  France;  at  a  third,  the  multiplication  of  taverns  and 
the  excessive  charges  demanded  by  the  sellers  of  wine. 
Throughout  there  is  a  prolonged  warfare  against  the  twin 
evils  of  extortionate  interest  and  extortionate  prices. 

Credit  was  an  issue  of  moment  at  Geneva,  not  merly  for 
the  same  reasons  which  made  it  a  burning  question  every- 
where to  the  small  producer  of  the  sixteenth  century,  but 
because,  especially  after  the  ruin  of  Lyons  in  the  French  wars 
of  religion,  the  city  was  a  financial  center  of  some  impor- 
tance. It  might  be  involved  in  war  at  any  moment.  In  order 
to  secure  command  of  the  necessary  funds,  it  had  borrowed 
heavily  from  Basle  and  Berne,  and  the  Council  used  the  cap- 
ital to  do  exchange  business  and  make  advances,  the  rate  of 
interest  being  fixed  at  10,  and  later  at  12,  per  cent.  To  the 
establishment  of  a  bank  the  ministers,  who  had  been  con- 
sulted, agreed;  against  the  profitable  business  of  advancing 
money  at  high  rates  of  interest  to  private  persons  they  pro-' 
tested,  especially  when  the  loans  were  made  to  spendthrifts 
who  used  them  to  ruin  themselves.  When,  ten  years  later,  in 
1580,  the  Council  approved  the  project  advanced  by  some 
company  promoters  of  establishing  a  second  bank  in  the 
city,  the  ministers  led  the  opposition  to  it,  pointed  to  the 
danger  of  covetousness  as  revealed  by  the  moral  corruption 
of  financial  cities  such  as  Paris,  Venice  and  Lyons,  and  sue- 


106  THE   CONTINENTAL   REFORMERS 

ceeded  in  getting  the  proposal  quashed.  Naturally,  however, 
the  commoner  issue  was  a  more  simple  one.  The  capitalist 
who  borrowed  in  order  to  invest  and  make  a  profit  could  take 
care  of  himself,  and  the  ministers  explained  that  they  had 
no  objection  to  those  "qui  baillent  leur  argent  aux  marchands 
pour  emploier  en  marchandise."  The  crucial  issue  was  that 
of  the  money-lender  who  makes  advances  "simplement  a  un 
qui  aura  besoin,"  and  who  thereby  exploits  the  necessities 
of  his  poorer  neighbors.72 

Against  monsters  of  this  kind  the  ministers  rage  without 
ceasing.  They  denounce  them  from  the  pulpit  in  the  name  of 
the  New  Testament,  in  language  drawn  principally  from  the 
less  temperate  portions  of  the  Old,  as  larrons,  brigands,  loups 
et  tigres,  who  ought  to  be  led  out  of  the  city  and  stoned  to 
death.  "The  poor  cry  and  the  rich  pocket  their  gains:  but 
what  they  are  heaping  up  for  themselves  is  the  wrath  of 
pod.  .  .  .  One  has  cried  in  the  market-place,  l  curse  on  those 
who  bring  us  dearth.'  .  .  .  The  Lord  has  heard  that  cry  ... 
and  yet  we  are  asking  the  cause  of  the  pestilence!  ...  A  cut- 
purse  shall  be  punished,  but  the  Lord  declares  by  his  prophet 
Amos  .  .  .  ' Famine  is  come  upon  my  people  of  Israel,  O  ye 
who  devour  the  poor.'  The  threats  there  uttered  have  been 
executed  against  his  people."  7<1  They  demand  that  for  his 
second  offense  the  usurer  shall  be  excommunicated,  or  that, 
if  such  a  punishment  be  thought  too  severe,  he  shall  at  least 
be  required  to  testify  his  repentance  publicly  in  church,  be- 
fore being  admitted  to  the  sacrament.  They  remind  their 
fellow-citizens  of  the  fate  of  Tyre  and  Sidon,  and,  momen- 
tarily despairing  of  controlling  the  money-lender  directly, 
they  propose  to  deprive  him  of  his  victims  by  removing  the 
causes  which  create  them.  Pour  tarir  les  ruisseaux  il  jaut 
escouper  la  source.  Men  borrow  because  of  "idleness,  foolish 
extravagance,  foolish  sins,  and  law  suits."  Let  censors  be  es- 
tablished at  Geneva,  as  in  Republican  Rome,  to  inquire, 
among  rich  as  well  as  among  poor,  how  each  household  earns 
its  livelihood,  to  see  that  all  children  of  ten  to  twelve  are 
taught  some  useful  trade,  to  put  down  taverns  and  litigation, 
and  to  "bridle  the  insatiable  avarice  of  those  who  are  such 
wretches  that  they  seek  to  enrich  themselves  by  the  neces- 
sities of  their  poor  neighbors."  74 

The  Venerable  Company  advanced  their  program,  but  they 
were  not  sanguine  that  it  would  be  carried  out,  and  they 


CALVIN  107 


concluded  it  by  expressing  to  the  City  Fathers  the 
hope,  not  wholly  free  from  irony,  that  "none  of  your  honor- 
able fellowship  may  be  found  spotted  with  such  vices."  Their 
apprehensions  were  justified.  The  Council  of  Geneva  endured 
many  things  at  the  hands  of  its  preachers,  till,  on  the  death 
of  Beza,  it  brought  them  to  heel.  But  there  were  limits  to  its 
patience,  and  it  was  in  the  field  of  business  ethics  that  they 
were  most  quickly  reached.  It  did  not  venture  to  question 
the  right  of  the  clergy  to  be  heard  on  matters  of  commerce 
and  finance.  The  pulpit  was  press  and  platform  in  one;  min- 
isters had  the  public  behind  them,  and,  conscious  of  their 
power,  would  in  the  last  resort  compel  submission  by  threat- 
ening to  resign  en  masse.  Profuse  in  expressions  of  sympa- 
thy, its  strategy  was  to  let  the  cannon  balls  of  Christian  So- 
cialism spend  themselves  on  the  yielding  down  of  official  pro- 
crastination, and  its  first  reply  was  normally  qu'on  y  pense 
un  pen.  To  the  clergy  its  inactivity  was  a  new  proof  of  com- 
plicity with  Mammon,  and  they  did  not  hesitate  to  declare 
their  indignation  from  the  pulpit.  In  1574  Beza  preached  a 
sermon  in  which  he  accused  members  of  the  Council  of  hav- 
ing intelligence  with  speculators  who  had  made  a  corner  in 
wheat.  Throughout  1577  the  ministers  were  reproaching  the 
Council  with  laxity  in  administration,  and  they  finally  de- 
nounced it  as  the  real  author  of  the  rise  in  the  prices  of  bread 
and  wine.  In  1579  they  addressed  to  it  a  memorandum,  set- 
ting out  a  new  scheme  of  moral  discipline  and  social  refornt 
The  prosperous  bourgeoisie  who  governed  Geneva  had  no 
objection  to  discouraging  extravagance  in  dress,  or  to  ex- 
horting the  public  to  attend  sermons  and  to  send  their  chil- 
dren to  catechism.  But  they  heard  denunciations  of  covetous- 
ness  without  enthusiasm,  and  on  two  matters  they  were  ob- 
durate. They  refused  to  check,  as  the  ministers  concerned 
to  lower  prices  had  demanded,  the  export  of  wine,  on  the 
ground  that  it  was  needed  in  order  to  purchase  imports  of 
wheat;  and,  as  was  natural  in  a  body  of  well-to-do  creditors, 
they  would  make  no  concession  to  the  complaint  that  debt- 
ors were  subjected  to  a  "double  usury,"  since  they  were  com- 
pelled to  repay  loans  in  an  appreciating  currency.  Money  fell 
as  well  as  rose,  they  replied,  and  even  the  late  M.  Calvin, 
by  whom  the  ordinance  now  criticized  had  been  approved, 
had  never  pushed  his  scruples  to  such  lengths.  Naturally,  the 
ministers  were  indignant  at  these  evasions.  They  informed 


108  £HE   CONTINENTAL  REFORMERS 

the  Council  that  large  sums  were  being  spent  by  speculators 
in  holding  up  supplies  of  corn,  and  launched  a  campaign  of 
sermons  against  avarice,  with  appropriate  topical  illustra- 
tions. Equally  naturally,  the  Council  retorted  by  accusing 
Beza  of  stirring  up  class  hatred  against  the  rich.75 

The  situation  was  aggravated  by  an  individual  scandal. 
One  of  the  magistrates,  who  regarded  Beza's  remarks  as  a 
personal  reflection,  was  rash  enough  to  demand  to  be  heard 
before  the  Council,  with  the  result  that  he  was  found  guilty, 
condemned  to  pay  a  fine,  and  compelled  to  forfeit  fifty 
crowns  which  he  had  lent  at  10  per  cent,  interest.  Evidently, 
when  matters  were  pushed  to  such  lengths  as  this,  no  one, 
however  respectable,  could  feel  sure  that  he  was  safe.  The 
Council  and  the  ministers  had  already  had  words  over  the 
sphere  of  their  respective  functions,  and  were  to  fall  out  a 
year  or  two  later  over  the  administration  of  the  local  hospi- 
tal. On  this  occasion  the  Council  complained  that  the  clergy 
were  interfering  with  the  magistrates'  duties,  and  implied 
politely  that  they  would  be  well  advised  to  mind  their  own 
business. 

So  monstrous  a  suggestion — as  though  there  were  any  hu- 
man activity  which  was  not  the  business  of  the  Church!  — 
evoked  a  counter-manifesto  on  the  part  of  the  ministers,  in 
which  the  full  doctrine  of  the  earthly  Jerusalem  was  set 
forth  in  all  its  majesty.  They  declined  to  express  regret  for 
having  cited  before  the  Consistory  those  who  sold  corn  at 
extortionate  prices,  and  for  refusing  the  sacrament  to  one 
of  them.  Did  not  Solomon  say,  "Cursed  is  who  keeps  his  corn 
in  time  of  scarcity"?  To  the  charge  of  intemperate  language 
Chauvet  replied  that  the  Council  had  better  begin  by  burn- 
ing the  books  of  the  Prophets,  for  he  had  done  no  more  than 
follow  the  example  set  by  Hosea.  "If  we  should  be  silent," 
said  Beza,  "what  would  the  people  say?  That  they  are  dumb 
dogs.  ...  As  to  the  question  of  causing  scandals,  for  the 
last  two  years  there  has  been  unceasing  talk  of  usury,  and, 
for  all  that,  no  more  than  three  or  four  usurers  have  been 
punished.  ...  It  is  notorious  everywhere  that  the  city  is  full 
of  usurers,  and  that  the  ordinary  rate  is  10  per  cent,  or 
more."  76  The  magistrates  renewed  their  remonstrances.  They 
had  seen  without  a  shudder  an  adulterer  condemned  to  be 
hanged,  and  had  mercifully  commuted  his  sentence  to  scourg- 
ing through  the  town,  followed  by  ten  years'  imprisonment 


CALVIN 

in  chains.77  But  at  the  godly  proposal  to  make  capitalists 
die  the  death  of  Achan  their  humanity  blenched.  Besides,  the 
punishment  was  not  only  cruel,  but  dangerous.  In  Geneva, 
"most  men  are  debtors."  If  they  are  allowed  to  taste  blood, 
who  can  say  where  their  fury  will  end?  Yet,  such  is  the 
power  of  the  spoken  word,  the  magistrates  did  not  venture 
on  a  blunt  refusal,  but  gave  scripture  for  scripture.  They  in- 
formed the  ministers  that  they  proposed  to  follow  the  exam- 
ple of  David,  who,  when  rebuked  by  Nathan,  confessed  his 
fault  Whether  the  ministers  replied  in  the  language  of  Na- 
than, we  are  not  informed. 

Recent  political  theory  has  been  prolific  in  criticisms  of 
the  omnicompetent  State.  The  principle  on  which  the  collec- 
tivism of  Geneva  rested  may  be  described  as  that  of  the  om- 
nicompetent Church.78  The  religious  community  formed  a 
closely  organized  society,  which,  while  using  the  secular  au- 
thorities as  police  officers  to  enforce  its  mandates,  not  only 
instructed  them  as  to  the  policy  to  be  pursued,  but  was  itself 
a  kind  of  State,  prescribing  by  its  own  legislation  the  stand- 
ard of  conduct  to  be  observed  by  its  members,  putting 
down  offenses  against  public  order  and  public  morals,  pro- 
viding for  the  education  of  youth  and  for  the  relief  of  the 
poor  The  peculiar  relations  between  the  ecclesiastical  and 
secular  authorities,  which  for  a  short  time  made  the  system 
possible  at  Geneva,  could  not  exist  to  the  same  degree  when 
Calvinism  was  the  creed,  not  of  a  single  city,  but  of  a  mi- 
nority in  a  national  State  organized  on  principles  quite  dif- 
ferent from  its  own.  Unless  the  State  itself  were  captured, 
rebellion,  civil  war  or  the  abandonment  of  the  pretension  to 
control  society  was  the  inevitable  consequence.  But  the  last 
result  was  long  delayed.  In  the  sixteenth  century,  whatever 
the  political  conditions,  the  claim  of  the  Calvinist  Churches 
is  everywhere  to  exercise  a  collective  responsibility  for  the 
moral  conduct  of  their  members  in  all  the  various  relations 
of  life,  and  to  do  so,  not  least,  in  the  sphere  of  economic 
transactions,  which  offer  peculiarly  insidious  temptations  to 
a  lapse  into  immorality. 

The  mantle  of  Calvin's  system  fell  earliest  upon  the  Re- 
formed Churches  of  France.  At  their  first  Synod,  held  in 
1559  at  Paris,  where  a  scheme  of  discipline  was  adopted, 
certain  difficult  matters  of  economic  casuistry  were  dis- 
cussed, and  similar  questions  continued  to  receive  attention 


t;10  THE   CONTINENTAL  REFORMERS 

at  subsequent  Synods  for  the  next  half-century,  until,  as  the 
historian  of  French  Calvinism  remarks,  "they  began  to  lax 
the  reins,  yielding  too  much  to  the  iniquity  of  the  time."  79 
Once  it  is  admitted  that  membership  of  the  Church  involves 
compliance  with  a  standard  of  economic  morality  which  the 
Church  must  enforce,  the  problems  of  interpretation  which 
arise  are  innumerable,  and  the  religious  community  finds  it- 
self committed  to  developing  something  like  a  system  of  case 
law,  by  the  application  of  its  general  principles  to  a  succes- 
sion of  varying  situations.  The  elaboration  of  such  a  system 
was  undertaken;  but  it  was  limited  in  the  sixteenth  century 
both  by  the  comparative  simplicity  of  the  economic  struc- 
ture, and  by  the  fact  that  the  Synods,  except  at  Geneva,  be- 
ing concerned  not  to  reform  society,  but  merely  to  repress 
the  grosser  kinds  of  scandal,  dealt  only  with  matters  on 
which  specific  guidance  was  demanded  by  the  Churches. 

Even  so,  however,  the  riddles  to  be  solved  were  not  a  few. 
What  is  to  be  the  attitutde  of  the  Churches  towards  those 
who  have  grown  rich  on  ill-gotten  wealth?  May  pirates  and 
fraudulent  tradesmen  be  admitted  to  the  Lord's  Supper? 
May  the  brethren  trade  with  such  persons,  or  do  they  share 
their  sin  if  they  buy  their  goods?  The  law  of  the  State  allows 
moderate  interest:  what  is  to  be  the  attitude  of  the  Church? 
What  is  to  be  done  to  prevent  craftsmen  cheating  the  con- 
sumer with  shoddy  wares,  and  tradesmen  oppressing  him 
with  extortionate  profits?  Are  lotteries  permissible?  Is  it  le- 
gitimate to  invest  at  interest  monies  bequeathed  for  the  ben- 
efit of  the  poor?  The  answers  which  the  French  Synods  made 
to  such  questions  show  the  persistence  of  the  idea  that  the 
transactions  of  business  are  the  province  of  the  Church,  com- 
bined with  a  natural  desire  to  avoid  an  impracticable  rigor. 
All  persons  who  have  wrung  wealth  unjustly  from  others 
must  make  restitution  before  they  be  admitted  to  com- 
munion, but  their  goods  may  be  bought  by  the  faithful,  pro- 
vided that  the  sale  is  public  and  approved  by  the  civil  au- 
thorities. Makers  of  fraudulent  wares  are  to  be  censured,  and 
tradesmen  are  to  seek  only  "indfferent  gain."  On  the  ques- 
tion of  usury,  the  same  division  of  opinion  is  visible  in  the 
French  Reformed  Church  as  existed  at  the  same  time  in 
England  and  Holland,  and  Calvin's  advice  on  the  subject 
was  requested.  The  stricter  school  would  not  hear  of  confin- 
ing the  prohibition  of  usury  to  "excessive  and  scandalous" 


CALVIN  111 

exactions,  or  of  raising  money  for  the  poor  by  interest  on 
capital.  In  France,  however,  as  elsewhere,  the  day  for  these 
heroic  rigors  had  passed,  and  the  common-sense  view  pre- 
vailed. The  brethren  were  required  to  demand  no  more  than 
the  law  allowed  and  than  was  consistent  with  charity.  With- 
in these  limits  interest  was  not  to  be  condemned.80 

Of  the  treatment  of  questions  of  this  order  by  English 
Puritanism  something  is  said  in  a  subsequent  chapter.  In 
Scotland  the  views  of  the  reformers  as  to  economic  ethics  did 
not  differ  in  substance  from  those  of  the  Church  before  the 
Reformation,  and  the  Scottish  Book  of  Discipline  denounced 
covetousness  with  the  same  vehemence  as  did  the  "accursed 
Popery"  which  it  had  overthrown.  Gentlemen  are  exhorted 
to  be  content  with  their  rents,  and  the  Churches  are  re- 
quired to  make  provision  for  the  poor.  "Oppression  of  the 
poor  by  exactions/'  it  is  declared,  "[and]  deceiving  of  them 
in  buying  or  selling  by  wrong  mete  or  measure  ...  do  prop- 
erly appertain  to  the  Church  of  God,  to  punish  the  same  as 
God's  word  commandeth." bl  The  interpretation  given  to 
these  offenses  is  shown  by  the  punishment  of  a  usurer  and 
of  a  defaulting  debtor  before  the  Kirk  Sessions  of  St.  An- 
drews.8- The  relief  of  the  poor  was  in  1579  made  the  statu- 
tory duty  of  ecclesiastical  authorities  in  Scotland,  seven 
years  after  it  had  in  England  been  finally  transferred  to  the 
State.  The  arrangement  under  which  in  rural  districts  it  re- 
posed down  to  1846  on  the  shoulders  of  ministers,  elders  and 
deacons,  was  a  survival  from  an  age  in  which  the  real  State 
in  Scotland  had  been  represented ,  not  by  Parliament  or 
Council,  but  by  the  Church  of  Knox. 

Of  English-speaking  communities,  that  in  which  the  social 
discipline  of  the  Calvinist  Church-State  was  carried  to  the 
furthest  extreme  was  the  Puritan  theocracy  of  New  Eng- 
land Its  practice  had  more  affinity  with  the  iron  rule  of 
Calvin's  Geneva  than  with  the  individualistic  tendencies  of 
contemporary  English  Puritanism.  In  that  happy,  bishopless 
Eden,  where  men  desired  only  to  worship  God  "according  to 
the  simplicitie  of  the  gospel  and  to  be  ruled  by  the  laws  of 
God's  word,"  83  not  only  were  "tobacco  and  immodest  fash- 
ions and  costly  apparel,"  and  "that  vain  custom  of  drinking 
to  one  another,"  forbidden  to  true  professors,  but  the 
Fathers  adopted  towards  that  "notorious  evil  .  .  .  whereby 
most  men  walked  in  all  their  commerce — to  buy  as  cheap 


J12  THE   CONTINENTAL  REFORMERS 

and  sell  as  dear  as  they  can," 8*  an  attitude  which  possibly 
would  not  be  wholly  congenial  to  their  more  businesslike 
descendants.  At  an  early  date  in  the  history  of  Massachu- 
setts a  minister  had  called  attention  to  the  recrudescence  of 
the  old  Adam — "profit  being  the  chief  aim  and  not  the 
propagation  of  religion" — and  Governor  Bradford,  observing 
uneasily  how  men  grew  "in  their  outward  estates,"  remarked 
that  the  increase  in  material  prosperity  "will  be  the  ruin  of 
New  England,  at  least  of  the  Churches  of  God  there."  85 
Sometimes  Providence  smote  the  exploiter.  The  immigrant 
who  organized  the  first  American  Trust — he  owned  the  only 
milch  cow  on  board  and  sold  the  milk  at  2d.  a  quart  "being 
after  at  a  sermon  wherein  oppression  was  complained  of  ... 
fell  distracted."  8C  Those  who  escaped  the  judgment  of  Hea- 
ven had  to  face  the  civil  authorities  and  the  Church,  which, 
in  the  infancy  of  the  colony,  were  the  same  thing. 

Naturally  the  authorities  regulated  prices,  limited  the  rate 
of  interest,  fixed  a  maximum  wage,  and  whipped  incorrigible 
idlers;  for  these  things  had  been  done  even  in  the  house  of 
bondage  from  which  they  fled.  What  was  more  distinctive 
of  the  children  of  light  was  their  attempt  to  apply  the  same 
wholesome  discipline  to  the  elusive  category  of  business 
profits.  The  price  of  cattle,  the  Massachusetts  authorities 
decreed,  was  to  be  determined,  not  by  the  needs  of  the  buyer, 
but  so  as  to  yield  no  more  than  a  reasonable  return  to  the 
seller.87  Against  those  who  charged  more,  their  wrath  was 
that  of  Moses  descending  to  find  the  chosen  people  worship- 
ping a  golden  calf.  What  little  emotion  they  had  to  spare 
from  their  rage  against  religious  freedom,  they  turned 
against  economic  license.  Roger  William  touched  a  real  affin- 
ity when,  in  his  moving  plea  for  tolerance,  he  argued  that, 
though  extortion  was  an  evil,  it  was  an  evil  the  treatment  of 
which  should  be  left  to  the  discretion  of  the  civil  authorities.88 

Consider  the  case  of  Mr.  Robert  Keane.  His  offense,  by 
general  consent,  was  black.  He  kept  a  shop  in  Boston,  in 
which  he  took  "in  some  .  .  .  above  6d.  in  the  shilling  profit; 
in  some  above  8c?.;  and  in  some  small  things  above  two  for 
one";  and  this,  though  he  was  "an  ancient  professor  of  the 
gospel,  a  man  of  eminent  parts,  wealthy  and  having  but  one 
child,  having  come  over  for  conscience'  sake  and  for  the  ad- 
vancement of  the  gospel."  The  scandal  was  terrible.  Profi- 
teers were  unpopular — "the  cry  of  the  country  was  great 


CALVIN  113 

against  oppression" — and  the  grave  elders  reflected  that  a 
reputation  for  greed  would  injure  the  infant  community,  ly- 
ing as  it  did  "under  the  curious  observation  of  all  Churches 
and  civil  States  in  the  world."  In  spite  of  all,  the  magistrates 
were  disposed  to  be  lenient.  There  was  no  positive  law  in 
force  limiting  profits;  it  was  not  easy  to  determine  what 
profits  were  fair;  the  sin  of  charging  what  the  market  could 
stand  was  not  peculiar  to  Mr.  Keane;  and,  after  all,  the  law 
of  God  required  no  more  than  double  restitution.  So  they 
treated  him  mercifully,  and  fined  him  only  £200. 

Here,  if  he  had  been  wise,  Mr.  Keane  would  have  let  the 
matter  drop.  But,  like  some  others  in  a  similar  position,  he 
damned  himself  irretrievably  by  his  excuses.  Summoned 
before  the  church  of  Boston,  he  first  of  all  "did  with  tears 
acknowledge  and  bewail  his  covetous  and  corrupt  heart," 
and  then  was  rash  enough  to  venture  on  an  explanation,  in 
which  he  argued  that  the  tradesman  must  live,  and  how 
could  he  live,  if  he  might  not  make  up  for  a  loss  on  one 
article  by  additional  profit  on  another?  Here  was  a  text  on 
which  no  faithful  pastor  could  refrain  from  enlarging.  The 
minister  of  Boston  pounced  on  the  opportunity,  and  took 
occasion  "in  his  public  exercise  the  next  lecture  day  to  lay 
open  the  error  of  such  false  principles,  and  to  give  some 
rules  of  direction  in  the  case.  Some  false  principles  were 
these. — 

ul.  That  a  man  might  sell  as  dear  as  he  can,  and  buy 
as  cheap  as  he  can. 

"2.  If  a  man  lose  by  casualty  of  sea,  etc.,  in  some  of  his 
commodities,  he  may  raise  the  price  of  the  rest. 

"3  That  he  may  sell  as  he  bought,  though  he  paid  too 
dear,  and  though  the  commodity  be  fallen,  etc. 

U4.  That,  as  a  man  may  take  the  advantage  of  his  own 
skill  or  ability,  so  he  may  of  another's  ignorance  or  neces- 
sity 

"5.  Where  one  gives  time  for  payment,  he  is  to  take  like 
recompense  of  one  as  of  another." 

The  rules  for  trading  were  not  less  explicit: — 

"1.  A  man  may  not  sell  above  the  current  price,  i.e., 
such  a  price  as  is  usual  in  the  time  and  place,  and  as  an* 
other  (who  knows  the  worth  of  the  commodity)  would  give 
for  it  if  he  had  occasion  to  use  it;  as  that  is  called  current 
money  which  every  man  will  take,  etc. 


114  THE  CONTINENTAL  REFORMERS 

"2.  When  a  man  loseth  in  his  commodity  for  want  of 
Skill,  etc.,  he  must  look  at  it  as  his  own  fault  or  cross,  and 
therefore  must  not  lay  it  upon  another. 

"3.  Where  a  man  loseth  by  casualty  of  sea,  etc.,  it  is  a 
loss  cast  upon  himself  by  Providence,  and  he  may  not  ease 
himself  of  it  by  casting  it  upon  another;  for  so  a  man 
should  seem  to  provide  against  all  providences,  etc.,  that 
he  should  never  lose;  but  where  there  is  a  scarcity  of  the 
commodity,  there  men  may  raise  their  price;  for  now  it  is  a 
hand  of  God  upon  the  commodity,  and  not  the  person. 

"4.  A  man  may  not  ask  any  more  for  his  commodity 
than  his  selling  price,  as  Ephron  to  Abraham:  the  land  is 
worth  thus  much." 

It  is  unfortunate  that  the  example  of  Ephron  was  not  re- 
membered in  the  case  of  transactions  affecting  the  lands  of 
Indians,  to  which  it  might  have  appeared  peculiarly  appro- 
priate. In  negotiating  with  these  children  of  the  devil,  how- 
ever, the  saints  of  God  considered  the  dealings  of  Israel 
with  Gibeon  a  more  appropriate  precedent. 

The  sermon  was  followed  by  an  animated  debate  within 
the  church.  It  was  moved,  amid  quotations  from  i  Cor.  v. 
n,  that  Mr.  Keane  should  be  excommunicated.  That  he 
might  be  excommunicated,  if  he  were  a  covetous  person 
within  the  meaning  of  the  text,  was  doubted  as  little  as  that 
he  had  recently  given  a  pitiable  exhibition  of  covetousness. 
The  question  was  only  whether  he  had  erred  through  ignor- 
ance or  carelessness,  or  whether  he  had  acted  "against  his 
conscience  or  the  very  light  of  nature" — whether,  in  short, 
his  sin  was  accidental  or  a  trade.  In  the  end  he  escaped  with 
his  fine  and  admonition.89 

If  the  only  Christian  documents  which  survived  were  the 
New  Testament  and  the  records  of  the  Calvin ist  Churches 
in  the  age  of  the  Reformation,  to  suggest  a  connection  be- 
tween them  more  intimate  than  a  coincidence  of  phraseology 
would  appear,  in  all  probability,  a  daring  extravagance. 
Legalistic,  mechanical,  without  imagination  or  compassion, 
the  work  of  a  jurist  and  organizer  of  genius,  Calvin's  sys- 
tem was  more  Roman  than  Christian,  and  more  Jewish  than 
either.  That  it  should  be  as  much  more  tyrannical  than  the 
medieval  Church,  as  the  Jacobin  Club  was  than  the  ancien 
regime,  was  inevitable.  Its  meshes  were  finer,  its  zeal  and 


CALVIN  11$ 

its  efficiency  greater.  And  its  enemies  were  not  merely  actions 
and  writings,  but  thoughts. 

The  tyranny  with  which  it  is  reproached  by  posterity 
would  have  been  regarded  by  its  champions  as  a  compli- 
ment. In  the  struggle  between  liberty  and  authority,  Cal- 
vinism sacrified  liberty,  not  with  reluctance,  but  with  en- 
thusiasm. For  the  Calvinist  Church  was  an  army  marching 
back  to  Canaan,  under  orders  delivered  once  for  all  from 
Sinai,  and  the  aim  of  its  leaders  was  the  conquest  of  the 
Promised  Land,  not  the  consolation  of  stragglers  or  the  en- 
couragement of  laggards.  In  war  the  classical  expedient  is 
a  dictatorship.  The  dictatorship  of  the  ministry  appeared 
as  inevitable  to  the  whole-hearted  Calvinist  as  the  Commit- 
tee of  Public  Safety  to  the  men  of  1793,  or  the  dictatorship 
of  the  proletariat  to  an  enthusiastic  Bolshevik.  If  it  reached 
its  zenith  where  Calvin's  discipline  was  accepted  without 
Calvin's  culture  and  intellectual  range,  in  the  orgies  of 
devil  worship  with  which  a  Cotton  and  an  Endicott  shocked 
at  last  even  the  savage  superstition  of  New  England,  that 
result  was  only  to  be  expected. 

The  best  that  can  be  said  of  the  social  theory  and  practice 
of  early  Calvinism  is  that  they  were  consistent.  Most  tyran- 
nies have  contented  themselves  with  tormenting  the  poor. 
Calvinism  had  little  pity  for  poverty;  but  it  distrusted 
wealth,  as  it  distrusted  all  influences  that  distract  the  aim 
or  relax  the  fibers  of  the  soul,  and,  in  the  first  flush  of  its 
youthful  austerity,  it  did  its  best  to  make  life  unbearable  fol 
the  rich.  Before  the  Paradise  of  earthly  comfort  it  hung  a 
flaming  brand,  waved  by  the  implacable  shades  of  Moses 
and  Aaron.')0 


CHAPTER  III 

The   Church   of  England 

"If  any  man  be  so  addicted  to  his  private,  that  he  neglect  the  com- 
mon, state,  he  is  void  of  the  sense  of  piety,  and  wisheth  peace  and 
happiness  to  himself  in  vain  For,  whoever  he  be,  he  must  live  in  the 
body  of  the  Commonwealth  and  in  the  body  of  the  Church  " 

LAUD,  Sermon  before  His  Majesty,  June  19,  1621. 

THE  ecclesiastical  and  political  controversies  which  descend 
from  the  sixteenth  century  have  thrust  into  oblivion  all 
issues  of  less  perennial  interest.  But  the  discussions  which 
were  motived  by  changes  in  the  texture  of  society  and  the 
relations  of  classes  were  keen  and  continuous,  nor  was  their 
result  without  significance  for  the  future.  In  England,  as  on 
the  Continent,  the  new  economic  realities  came  into  sharp 
collision  with  the  social  theory  inherited  from  the  Middle 
Ages.  The  result  was  a  re-assertion  of  the  traditional  doc- 
trines with  an  almost  tragic  intensity  of  emotion,  their 
gradual  retreat  before  the  advance  of  new  conceptions,  both 
of  economic  organization  and  of  the  province  of  religion, 
and  their  final  decline  from  a  militant  creed  into  a  kind  of 
pious  antiquarianism.  They  lingered,  venerable  ghosts,  on 
the  lips  of  churchmen  down  to  the  Civil  War.  Then  the 
storm  blew  and  they  flickered  out. 

Medieval  England  had  lain  on  the  outer  edge  of  economic 
civilization,  remote  from  the  great  highways  of  commerce 
and  the  bustling  financial  centers  of  Italy  and  Germany. 
With  the  commercial  revolution  which  followed  the  Discov- 
eries, a  new  age  began  After  the  first  outburst  of  curiosity, 
interest  in  explorations  which  yielded  no  immediate  return 
of  treasure  died  down.  It  was  not  till  more  than  half  a  cen- 
tury later,  when  the  silver  of  the  New  World  was  dazzling 
all  Europe,  that  Englishmen  reflected  that  it  might  conceiv- 
ably have  been  lodged  in  the  Tower  instead  of  at  Seville, 
and  that  talk  of  competition  for  America  and  the  East  be- 
gan in  earnest. 

In  the  meantime,  however,  every  other  aspect  of  English 
economic  life  was  in  process  of  swift  transformation.  Fo- 
eign  trade  increased  largely  in  the  first  half  of  the  sixteenth 

116 


THE   CHURCH   OF   ENGLAND  U? 

century,  and,  as  manufactures  developed,  cloth  displaced 
wool  as  the  principal  export.  With  the  growth  of  commerce 
went  the  growth  of  the  financial  organization  on  which  com- 
merce depends,  and  English  capital  poured  into  the  growing 
London  money-market,  which  had  previously  been  dom- 
inated by  Italian  bankers.  At  home,  with  the  expansion  of 
internal  trade  which  followed  the  Tudor  peace,  opportunities 
of  speculation  were  increased,  and  a  new  class  of  middlemen 
arose  to  exploit  them.  In  industry,  the  rising  interest  was 
that  of  the  commercial  capitalist,  bent  on  securing  the  free- 
dom to  grow  to  what  stature  he  could,  and  produce  by 
what  methods  he  pleased.  Hampered  by  the  defensive  ma- 
chinery of  the  gilds,  with  their  corporate  discipline,  their 
organized  torpor  restricting  individual  enterprise,  and  their 
rought  equalitarianism,  either  he  quietly  evaded  gild  regu- 
lations by  withdrawing  from  the  corporate  towns,  within 
which  alone  the  pressure  of  economic  conformity  could  be 
made  effective,  or  he  accepted  the  gild  organization,  cap- 
tured its  government,  and  by  means  of  it  developed  a  system 
under  which  the  craftsman,  even  if  nominally  a  master,  was 
in  effect  the  servant  of  an  employer.  In  agriculture,  the 
customary  organization  of  the  village  was  being  sapped  from 
below  and  battered  down  from  above  For  a  prosperous 
peasantry,  who  had  commuted  the  labor  services  that  were 
still  the  rule  in  France  and  Germany,  were  rearranging  their 
strips  by  exchange  or  agreement,  and  lords,  no  longer  petty 
sovereigns,  but  astute  business  men,  were  leasing  their 
demesnes  to  capital  farmers,  quick  to  grasp  the  profits  to 
be  won  by  sheep-grazing,  and  eager  to  clear  away  the  net- 
work of  communal  restrictions  which  impeded  its  extension. 
Into  commerce,  industry  and  agriculture  alike,  the  revolu- 
tion in  prices,  gradual  for  the  first  third  of  the  centry,  but 
after  1540  a  mill  race,  injected  a  virus  of  hitherto  unsus- 
pected potency,  at  once  a  stimulant  to  feverish  enterprise 
and  an  acid  dissolving  all  customary  relationships. 

It  was  a  society  in  rapid  motion,  swayed  by  new  ambi- 
tions and  haunted  by  new  terrors,  in  which  both  success  and 
failure  had  changed  their  meaning.  Except  in  the  turbulent 
north,  the  aim  of  the  great  landowner  was  no  longer  to  hold 
at  his  call  an  army  of  retainers,  but  to  exploit  his  estates  as 
a  judicious  investment.  The  prosperous  merchant,  once  con- 
tent to  win  a  position  of  dignity  and  power  in  fraternity  or 


118  THE   CHURCH    OF   ENGLAND 

town,  now  flung  himself  into  the  task  of  carving  his  way  to 
solitary  preeminence,  unaided  by  the  artificial  protection  of 
guild  or  city.  To  the  immemorial  poverty  of  peasant  and 
craftsman,  pitting,  under  the  ever-present  threat  of  famine, 
their  pigmy  forces  against  an  implacable  nature,  was  added 
the  haunting  insecurity  of  a  growing,  though  still  small, 
proletariat,  detached  from  their  narrow  niche  in  village  or 
borough,  the  sport  of  social  forces  which  they  could  neither 
understand,  nor  arrest,  nor  control. 

I.    THE  LAND  QUESTION 

The  England  of  the  Reformation,  to  which  posterity  turns 
as  a  source  of  high  debates  on  church  government  and  doc- 
trine, was  to  contemporaries  a  cauldron  seething  with  eco- 
nomic unrest  and  social  passions.  But  the  material  on  which 
agitation  fed  had  been  accumulating  for  three  generations, 
and  of  the  grievances  which  exploded  in  the  middle  of  the 
century,  with  the  exception  of  the  depreciation  of  the  cur- 
rency, there  was  not  one — neither  enclosures  and  pasture 
farming,  nor  usury,  nor  the  malpractices  of  gilds,  nor  the 
rise  in  prices,  nor  the  oppression  of  craftsmen  by  merchants, 
nor  the  extortions  of  the  engrosser — which  had  not  evoked 
popular  protests,  been  denounced  by  publicists,  and  pro- 
duced legislation  and  administrative  action,  long  before  the 
Reformation  Parliament  met.  The  floods  were  already  run- 
ning high,  when  the  religious  revolution  swelled  them  with 
a  torrent  of  bitter,  if  bracing,  waters.  Its  effect  on  the  social 
situation  was  twofold.  Since  it  produced  a  sweeping  redis- 
tribution of  wealth,  carried  out  by  an  unscrupulous  minority 
using  the  weapons  of  violence,  intimidation  and  fraud,  and 
succeeded  by  a*i  orgy  of  interested  misgovernment  on  the 
part  of  its  principal  beneficiaries,  it  aggravated  every  prob- 
lem, and  gave  a  new  turn  to  the  screw  which  was  squeezing 
peasant  and  craftsman.  Since  it  released  a  torrent  of  writ- 
ing on  questions  not  only  of  religion,  but  of  social  organ- 
ization, it  caused  the  criticisms  passed  on  the  changes  of 
the  past  half-century  to  be  brought  to  a  head  in  a  sweeping 
indictment  of  the  new  economic  forces  and  an  eloquent 
restatement  of  the  traditional  theory  of  social  obligations. 
The  center  of  both  was  the  land  question.  For  it  was  agra- 


THE  LAND  QUESTION  119 

rian  plunder  which  principally  stirred  the  cupidity  of  the 
age,  and  agrarian  grievances  which  were  the  most  important 
ground  of  social  agitation. 

The  land  question  had  been  a  serious  matter  for  the  great- 
er part  of  a  century  before  the  Reformation.  The  first  de- 
tailed account  of  enclosure  had  been  written  by  a  chantry 
priest  in  Warwickshire,  soon  after  1460  l  Then  had  come 
the  legislation  of  1489,  1515  and  1516,  Wolsey's  Royal  Com- 
mission in  1517,  and  more  legislation  in  1534.2  Throughout, 
a  steady  stream  of  criticism  had  flowed  from  men  of  the 
Renaissance,  like  More,  Starkey  and  a  host  of  less  well- 
known  writers,  dismayed  at  the  advance  of  social  anarchy, 
and  sanguine  of  the  miracles  to  be  performed  by  a  Prince 
who  would  take  counsel  of  philosophers. 

If,  however,  the  problem  was  acute  long  before  the  con- 
fiscation of  the  monastic  estates,  its  aggravation  by  the  fury 
of  spoilation  let  loose  by  Henry  and  Cromwell  is  not  open 
to  serious  question.  It  is  a  mistake,  no  doubt,  to  see  the  last 
days  of  monasticism  through  rose-colored  spectacles.  The 
monks,  after  all,  were  business  men,  and  the  lay  agents 
whom  they  often  employed  to  manage  their  property  nat- 
urally conformed  to  the  agricultural  practice  of  the  world 
around  them.  In  Germany  revolts  were  nowhere  more  fre- 
quent or  more  bitter  than  on  the  estates  of  ecclesiastical 
land-owners.3  In  England  a  glance  at  the  proceedings  of  the 
Courts  of  Star  Chamber  and  Requests  is  enough  to  show 
that  holy  men  reclaimed  villeins,  turned  copy-holders  into 
tenants  at  will,  and  as  More  complained,  converted  arable 
land  to  pasture.4 

In  reality,  the  supposition  of  unnatural  virtue  on  the  part 
of  the  monks,  or  of  more  than  ordinary  harshness  on  the 
part  of  the  new  proprietors,  is  not  needed  in  order  to  ex- 
plain the  part  which  the  rapid  transference  of  great  masses 
of  property  played  in  augmenting  rural  distress.  The  worst 
side  of  all  such  sudden  and  sweeping  redistributions  is  that 
the  individual  is  more  or  less  at  the  mercy  of  the  market, 
and  can  hardly  help  taking  his  pound  of  flesh.  Estates  with 
a  capital  value  (in  terms  of  modern  money)  of  £15,000,000 
to  £20,000,000  changed  hands.5  To  the  abbey  lands  which 
came  into  the  market  after  1536  were  added  those  of  the 
gilds  and  chantries  in  1547.  The  financial  necessities  of  the 


129  THE   CHURCH   OF   ENGLAND 

Crown  were  too  pressing  to  allow  of  its  retaining  them  in 
its  own  possession  and  drawing  the  rents;  nor,  in  any  case, 
would  that  have  been  the  course  dictated  by  prudence  to  a 
Government  which  required  a  party  to  carry  through  a  revo- 
lution. What  it  did,  therefore,  was  to  alienate  most  of  the 
land  almost  immediately,  and  to  spend  the  capital  as  in- 
come. For  a  decade  there  was  a  mania  of  land  speculation. 
Much  of  the  property  was  bought  by  needy  courtiers,  at  a 
ridiculously  low  figure.  Much  of  it  passed  to  sharp  business 
men,  who  brought  to  bear  on  its  management  the  methods 
learned  in  the  financial  school  of  the  City;  the  largest  single 
grantee  was  Sir  Richard  Gresham.  Much  was  acquired  by 
middlemen,  who  bought  scattered  parcels  of  land,  held  them 
for  the  rise,  and  disposed  of  them  piecemeal  when  they  got 
a  good  offer;  in  London,  groups  of  tradesmen — cloth-work- 
ers, leather-sellers,  merchant  tailors,  brewers,  tallow-chand- 
lers— formed  actual  syndicates  to  exploit  the  market.  Rack- 
renting,  evictions,  and  the  conversions  of  arable  to  pasture 
were  the  natural  result,  for  surveyors  wrote  up  values  at 
each  transfer,  and,  unless  the  last  purchaser  squeezed  his 
tenants,  the  transaction  would  not  pay.6 

Why,  after  all,  should  a  landlord  be  more  squeamish 
than  the  Crown?  "Do  ye  not  know,"  said  the  grantee  of 
one  of  the  Sussex  manors  of  the  monastery  of  Sion,  in  an- 
swer to  some  peasants  who  protested  at  the  seizure  of  their 
commons,  "that  the  King's  Grace  hath  put  down  all  the 
houses  of  monks,  friars  and  nuns?  Therefore  now  is  the  time 
come  that  we  gentlemen  will  pull  down  the  houses  of  such 
poor  knaves  as  ye  be."  1  Such  arguments,  if  inconsequent, 
were  too  convenient  not  to  be  common.  The  protests  of  con- 
temporaries receive  detailed  confirmation  from  the  bitter 
struggles  which  can  be  traced  between  the  peasanty  and 
some  of  the  new  landlords — the  Herberts,  who  enclosed  a 
whole  village  to  make  the  park  at  Washerne,  in  which, 
according  to  tradition,  the  gentle  Sidney  was  to  write  his 
Arcadia,  the  St.  Johns  at  Abbot's  Ripton,  and  Sir  John 
Yorke,  third  in  the  line  of  speculators  in  the  lands  of  Whitby 
Abbey,  whose  tenants  found  their  rents  raised  from  ,£29 
to  £64  a  year,  and  for  nearly  twenty  years  were  besieging 
the  Government  with  petitions  for  redress.8  The  legend, 
still  repeated  late  in  the  seventeenth  century,  that  the 


THE  LAND   QUESTION  121 

grantees  of  monastic  estates  died  out  in  three  generations, 
though  unveracious,  is  not  surprising.  The  wish  was  father 
to  the  thought. 

It  was  an  age  in  which  the  popular  hatred  of  the  endoser 
and  the  engrosser  found  a  natural  ally  in  religious  senti- 
ment, schooled,  as  it  was,  in  a  tradition  which  had  taught 
that  the  greed  of  gain  was  a  deadly  sin,  and  that  the  plea 
of  economic  self-interest  did  not  mitigate  the  verdict,  but 
aggravated  the  offence.  In  England,  as  on  the  Continent, 
doctrinal  radicalism  marched  hand  in  hand  with  social  con- 
servatism. The  most  scathing  attack  on  social  disorders 
came,  not  from  the  partisans  of  the  old  religion,  but  from 
divines  on  the  left  wing  of  the  Protestant  party,  who  saw 
in  economic  individualism  but  another  expression  of  the 
laxity  and  license  which  had  degraded  the  purity  of  religion, 
and  who  understood  by  reformation  a  return  to  the  moral 
austerity  of  the  primitive  Church,  no  less  than  to  its  gov- 
ernment and  doctrine.  The  touching  words  9  in  which  the 
leader  of  the  Pilgrimage  of  Grace  painted  the  social  effects 
of  the  dissolution  of  the  Yorkshire  monasteries  were  mild 
compared  with  the  denunciations  launched  ten  years  later 
by  Latimer,  Crowley,  Lever,  Becon  and  Ponet. 

Their  passion  was  natural.  What  Aske  saw  in  the  green 
tree,  they  saw  in  the  dry,  and  their  horror  at  the  plunge 
into  social  immorality  was  sharpened  by  the  bitterness  of 
disappointed  hopes.  It  was  all  to  have  been  so  different! 
The  movement  which  produced  the  Reformation  was  a 
Janus,  not  with  two,  but  with  several,  faces,  and  among 
them  had  been  one  which  looked  wistfully  for  a  political 
and  social  regeneration  as  the  fruit  of  the  regeneration  of 
religion.10  In  England,  as  in  Germany  and  Switzerland,  men 
had  dreamed  of  a  Reformation  which  would  reform  the 
State  and  society,  as  well  as  the  Church.  The  purification, 
not  merely  of  doctrine,  but  of  morals,  the  encouragement  of 
learning,  the  diffusion  of  education,  the  relief  of  poverty,  by 
the  stirring  into  life  a  mass  of  sleeping  endowments,  a  spirit- 
ual and  social  revival  inspired  by  the  revival  of  the  faith  of 
the  Gospel — such,  not  without  judicious  encouragement 
from  a  Government  alert  to  play  on  public  opinion,  was  the 
vision  which  had  floated  before  the  eyes  of  the  humanitarian 
and  the  idealist. 


J:22  THE   CHURCH   OF  ENGLAND 

It  did  not  vanish  without  a  struggle.  At  the  very  height 
of  the  economic  crisis,  Bucer,  the  tutor  of  Edward  VI,  and 
Professor  of  Divinity  at  Cambridge,  stated  the  social  pro- 
gram of  a  Christian  renaissance  in  the  manual  of  Christian 
politics  which  he  drafted  in  order  to  explain  to  his  pupil 
how  the  Kingdom  of  Christ  might  be  established  by  a 
Christian  prince.  Its  outlines  were  sharpened,  and  its  details 
elaborated,  with  all  the  remorseless  precision  of  a  disciple 
of  Calvin.  Willful  idlers  are  to  be  excommunicated  by  the 
Church  and  punished  by  the  State.  The  Government,  a  pious 
mercantilist,  is  to  revive  the  woollen  industry,  to  introduce 
the  linen  industry,  to  insist  on  pasture  being  put  under  the 
plow.  It  is  to  take  a  high  line  with  the  commercial  classes. 
For,  though  trade  itself  is  honorable,  most  traders  are 
rogues — indeed  "next  to  the  sham  priests,  no  class  of  men 
is  more  pestilential  to  the  Commonwealth";  their  works  are 
usury,  monopolies,  and  the  bribery  of  Governments  to  over- 
look both.  Fortunately,  the  remedies  are  simple.  The  State 
must  fix  just  prices — "a  very  necessary  but  an  easy  matter/' 
Only  "pious  persons,  devoted  to  the  Commonwealth  more 
than  to  their  own  interests/'  are  to  be  allowed  to  engage 
in  trade  at  all.  In  every  village  and  town  a  school  is  to  be 
established  under  a  master  eminent  for  piety  and  wisdom. 
"Christian  princes  must  above  all  things  strive  that  men  of 
virtue  may  abound,  and  live  to  the  glory  of  God.  .  .  . 
Neither  the  Church  of  Christ,  nor  a  Christian  Common- 
wealth, ought  to  tolerate  such  as  prefer  private  gain  to  the 
public  weal,  or  seek  it  to  the  hurt  of  their  neighbors."  " 

The  Christian  prince  strove,  but  not,  poor  child,  as  those 
that  prevail.  The  classes  whose  backing  was  needed  to  make 
the  Reformation  a  political  success  had  sold  their  support 
on  terms  which  made  it  inevitable  that  it  should  be  a  social 
disaster.  The  upstart  aristocracy  of  the  future  had  their 
teeth  in  the  carcass,  and,  having  tasted  blood,  they  were  not 
to  be  whipped  off  by  a  sermon.  The  Government  of  Edward 
VI,  like  all  Tudor  Governments,  made  its  experiment  in  fix- 
ing just  prices.  What  the  astute  Gresham,  its  financial  ad- 
viser, thought  of  restricting  commerce  to  persons  of  piety, 
we  do  not  know,  but  can  guess.  As  for  the  schools,  what  it 
did  for  them  Mr.  Leach  has  told  us.  It  swept  them  away 
wholesale  in  order  to  distribute  their  endowments  among 


THE   LAND   QUESTION  123 

courtiers.  There  were  probably  more  schools  m  proportion 
to  the  population  at  the  end  of  the  fifteenth  century  than 
there  were  in  the  middle  of  the  nineteenth.  "These  endow- 
ments were  confiscated  by  the  State,  and  many  still  line  the 
pockets  of  the  descendants  of  the  statesmen  of  the  day."  ia 
"King  Edward  VPs  Grammar  Schools"  are  the  schools  which 
King  Edward  VI  did  not  destroy. 

The  disillusionment  was  crushing.  Was  it  surprising  that 
the  reformers  should  ask  what  had  become  of  the  devout 
imaginations  of  social  righteousness,  which  were  to  have 
been  relalized  as  the  result  of  a  godly  reformation?  The  end 
of  Popery,  the  curtailment  of  ecclesiastical  privileges,  six 
new  bishoprics,  lectureships  in  Greek  and  Latin  in  place  of 
the  disloyal  subject  of  the  canon  law,  the  reform  of  doctrine 
and  ritual — side  by  side  with  these  good  things  had  come 
some  less  edifying  changes,  the  ruin  of  much  education,  the 
cessation  of  much  charity,  a  raid  on  corporate  property 
which  provoked  protests  even  in  the  House  of  Commons,13 
and  for  ten  years  a  sinister  hum,  as  of  the  floating  of  an 
immense  land  syndicate,  with  favorable  terms  for  all  suffi- 
ciently rich,  or  influential,  or  mean,  to  get  in  on  the  ground 
floor.  Then  men  who  had  invested  in  the  Reformation  when 
it  was  still  a  gambling  stock  naturally  nursed  the  security, 
and  denounced  the  revolting  peasants  as  communists,  with 
the  mystical  reverence  for  the  rights  of  property  which  is 
characteristic  in  all  ages  of  the  nouvcaux  riches.14  The  men 
whose  religion  was  not  money  said  what  they  thought  of 
the  business  in  pamphlets  and  sermons,  which  left  respect- 
able congregations  spluttering  with  fury. 

Crowley  pilloried  lease-mongers  and  usurers,  wrote  that 
the  sick  begged  in  the  street  because  rich  men  had  seized 
the  endowments  of  hospitals,  and  did  not  conceal  his  sym- 
pathy with  the  peasants  who  rose  under  Ket.15  Becon  told 
the  gentry,  eloquent  on  the  vices  of  abbey-lubbers,  that  the 
only  difference  between  them  and  the  monks  was  that  they 
were  more  greedy  and  more  useless,  more  harsh  in  wringing 
the  last  penny  from  the  tenants,  more  selfish  in  spending 
the  whole  income  on  themselves,  more  pitiless  to  the  poor.1* 
"In  suppressing  of  abbies,  cloisters,  colleges  and  chantries," 
preached  Lever  in  St.  Paul's,  "the  intent  of  the  King's  Maj- 
esty that  dead  is,  was,  and  of  this  our  king  now  is,  very 


124  THE   CHURCH   OF  ENGLAND 

godly,  and  the  purpose,  or  else  the  pretence,  of  other  won- 
drous goodly:  that  thereby  such  abundance  of  goods  as  was 
superstitiously  spent  upon  vain  ceremonies,  or  voluptuously 
upon  idle  bellies,  might  come  to  the  king's  hands  to  bear  his 
great  charges,  necessarily  bestowed  in  the  common  wealth, 
or  partly  unto  other  men's  hands,  for  the  better  relief  of 
the  poor,  the  maintenance  of  learning,  and  the  setting  forth 
of  God's  word.  Howbeit,  covetous  officers  have  so  used  this 
matter,  that  even  those  goods  which  did  serve  to  the  relief 
of  the  poor,  the  maintenance  of  learning,  and  to  comfortable 
necessary  hospitality  in  the  common  wealth,  be  now  turned 
to  maintain  worldly,  wicked,  covetous  ambition.  .  .  .  You 
which  have  gotten  these  goods  into  your  own  hands,  to  turn 
them  from  evil  to  worse,  and  other  goods  more  from  good 
unto  evil,  be  ye  sure  it  is  even  you  that  have  offended  God, 
beguiled  the  king,  robbed  the  rich,  spoiled  the  poor,  and 
brought  a  common  wealth  into  a  common  misery."  17 

This  was  plain  speaking  indeed.  Known  to  their  enemies 
as  the  "Commonwealth  men"  from  their  advocacy  of  social 
reconstruction,  the  group  of  which  Latimer  was  the  prophet 
and  Hales  the  man  of  action  naturally  incurred  the  charge 
of  stirring  up  class-hatred,  which  is  normally  brought  against 
all  who  call  attention  to  its  causes.  The  result  of  their  ac- 
tivity was  the  appointment  of  a  Royal  Commission  to 
inquire  into  offences  against  the  Acts  forbidding  the  con- 
version of  arable  to  pasture,  the  introduction  of  legislation 
requiring  the  maintenance  of  tillage  and  rebuilding  of  cot- 
tages, and  a  proclamation  pardoning  persons  who  had  taken 
the  law  into  their  own  hands  by  pulling  down  hedges.  The 
gentry  were  furious.  Paget,  the  secretary  to  the  Council, 
who  was  quite  ready  for  a  reign  of  terror,  provided  that  the 
gentlemen  began  it,  prophesied  gloomily  that  the  German 
Peasants'  War  was  to  be  reenacted  in  England;  the  Council, 
most  of  whose  members  held  abbey  lands,  was  sullen;  and 
Warwick,  the  personification  of  the  predatory  property  of 
the  day,  attacked  Hales  fiercely  for  carrying  out,  as  chair- 
man of  the  Midland  committee  of  the  Depopulation  Com- 
mission, the  duties  laid  upon  him  by  the  Government.  "Sir," 
wrote  a  plaintiff  gentleman  to  Cecil,  "be  plain  with  my 
Lord's  Grace,  that  under  the  pretense  of  simplicity  and 
poverty  there  may  [not]  rest  much  mischief.  So  do  I  fear 
there  doth  in  these  men  called  Common  Wealths  and  their 


THE   LAND   QUESTION  125 

adherents.  To  declare  unto  you  the  state  of  the  gentlemen 
(I  mean  as  well  the  greatest  as  the  lowest),  I  assure  yoti 
they  are  in  such  doubt,  that  almost  they  dare  touch  none 
of  them  [i.e.,  the  peasants],  not  for  that  they  are  afraid  of 
them,  but  for  that  some  of  them  have  been  pent  up  and  come 
away  without  punishment,  and  that  Common  Wealth  called 
Latimer  hath  gotten  the  pardon  of  others."18 
^  The  "Common  Wealth  called  Latimer"  was  unrepentant. 
Combining  gifts  of  humor  and  invective  which  are  not  very 
common  among  bishops,  his  fury  at  oppression  did  not  pre- 
vent him  from  greeting  the  Devil  with  a  burst  of  uproarious 
laughter,  as  of  a  satyrical  gargoyle  carved  to  make  the  sin- 
ner ridiculous  in  this  world  before  he  is  damned  in  the  next. 
So  he  was  delighted  when  he  provoked  one  of  his  audience 
into  the  exclamation,  "Mary,  a  seditious  fellow!"  used  the 
episode  as  comic  relief  in  his  next  sermon,19  and  then,  sud- 
denly serious,  redoubled  his  denunciations  of  step-lords  and 
rent-raisers.  Had  not  the  doom  of  the  covetous  been  pro- 
nounced by  Christ  Himself? 

You  Ihoughte  that  I  woulde  not  icquyre 
The  bloode  of  all  suche  at  your  handc, 
Bui  be  you  sure,  etcrnall  fyre 
Is  redy  for  cche  hell  fyicbrande 
Both  for  the  housynge  and  the  lande 
That  you  have  taken  from  the  pore 
Ye  shall  in  hell  dwell  evermore  J0 

On  the  technicalities  of  the  Tudor  land  question  the  au- 
thors of  such  outbursts  spoke  without  authority,  and,  thanks 
to  Mr.  Leadam  and  Professor  Gay,  modern  research  has 
found  no  difficulty  in  correcting  the  perspective  of  their 
story.  At  once  incurious  and  ill-informed  as  to  the  large 
impersonal  causes  which  were  hurrying  forward  the  reorgan- 
ization of  agriculture  on  a  commercial  basis,  what  shocked 
them  was  not  only  the  material  misery  of  their  age,  but  its 
repudiation  of  the  principles  by  which  alone,  as  it  seemed, 
human  society  is  distinguished  from  a  pack  of  wolves.  Their 
enemy  was  not  merely  the  Northumberlands  or  Herberts, 
but  an  idea,  and  they  sprang  to  the  attack,  less  of  spoliation 
or  tyranny,  than  of  a  creed  which  was  the  parent  of  both. 
That  creed  was  that  the  individual  is  absolute  master  of 
his  own,  and,  within  the  limits  set  by  positive  law,  may 


t26  THE   CHURCH   OP   ENGLAND 

exploit  it  with  a  single  eye  to  his  pecuniary  advantage,  un- 
restrained by  any  obligation  to  postpone  his  own  profit  to 
the  well-being  of  his  neighbors,  or  to  give  account  of  his  ac- 
tions to  a  higher  authority.  It  was,  in  short,  the  theory  of 
property  which  was  later  to  be  accepted  by  all  civilized 
communities. 

The  question  of  the  respective  rights  of  lord  and  peasant 
had  never,  at  least  within  recent  centuries,  arisen  in  so  acute 
a  form,  for,  as  long  as  the  customary  tenants  were  part  of 
the  stock  of  the  manor,  it  was  obviously  to  the  interest 
of  the  lord  to  bind  them  to  the  soil.  Now  all  that  had  been 
changed,  at  any  rate  in  the  south  and  midlands,  by  the  ex- 
pansion of  the  woollen  industry  and  the  devaluation  of 
money.  Chevage  and  merchet  had  gone;  forced  labor,  if  it 
had  not  gone,  was  fast  going.  The  psychology  of  landowning 
had  been  revolutionized,  and  for  two  generations  the  sharp 
landlord,  instead  of  using  his  seigneurial  right  to  fine  or 
arrest  run-aways  from  the  villein  nest,  had  been  hunting 
for  flaws  in  titles,  screwing  up  admission  fines,  twisting 
manorial  customs,  and,  when  he  dared,  turning  copyholds 
into  leases.  The  official  opposition  to  depopulation,  which 
had  begun  in  1489  and  was  to  last  almost  till  1640,  infuri- 
ated him,  as  an  intolerable  interference  with  the  rights  of 
property.  In  their  attacks  on  the  restraints  imposed  by  vil- 
lage custom  from  below  and  by  the  Crown  from  above,  in 
their  illegal  defiance  of  the  statutes  forbidding  depopulation, 
and  in  their  fierce  resistance  to  the  attempts  of  Wolsey  and 
Somerset  to  restore  the  old  order,  the  interests  which  were 
making  the  agrarian  revolution  were  watering  the  seeds  of 
that  individualistic  conception  of  ownership  which  was  to 
carry  all  before  it  after  the  Civil  War.  With  such  a  doctrine, 
since  it  denied  both  the  existence  and  the  necessity  of  a 
moral  title,  it  was  not  easy  for  any  religion  less  pliant  than 
that  of  the  eighteenth  century  to  make  a  truce.  Once  ac- 
cepted, it  was  to  silence  the  preaching  of  all  social  duties 
save  that  of  submission.  If  property  be  an  unconditional 
right,  emphasis  on  its  obligations  is  little  more  than  the 
graceful  parade  of  a  flattering,  but  innocuous,  metaphor. 
For,  whether  the  obligations  are  fulfilled  or  neglected,  the 
right  continues  unchallenged  and  indefeasible.  ' 

A  religious  theory  of  society  necessarily  regards  with  sus- 
picion all  doctrines  which  claim  a  large  space  for  the  unfet- 


THE  LAND   QUESTION 

tered  play  of  economic  self-interest.  To  the  latter  the 
of  activity  is  the  satisfaction  of  desires,  to  the  former  the 
felicity  of  man  consists  in  the  discharge  of  obligations  im- 
posed by  God.  Viewing  the  social  order  as  the  imperfect 
reflection  of  a  divine  plan,  it  naturally  attaches  a  high  value 
to  the  arts  by  which  nature  is  harnessed  to  the  service  of 
mankind.  But,  more  concerned  with  ends  than  with  means, 
it  regards  temporal  goods  as  at  best  instrumental  to  a 
spiritual  purpose,  and  its  standpoint  is  that  of  Bacon,  when 
he  spoke  of  the  progress  of  knowledge  as  being  sought  for 
"the  glory  of  the  Creator  and  the  relief  of  man's  estate." 
To  a  temper  nurtured  on  such  ideas,  the  new  agrarian 
regime,  with  its  sacrifice  of  the  village — a  fellowship  of 
mutual  aid,  a  partnership  of  service  and  protection,  "a  little 
commonwealth" — to  the  pecuniary  interests  of  a  great  pro- 
prietor, who  made  a  desert  where  men  had  worked  and 
prayed,  seemed  a  defiance,  not  only  of  man,  but  of  God, 
It  was  the  work  of  "men  that  live  as  thoughe  there  were  no 
God  at  all,  men  that  would  have  all  in  their  owne  handes, 
men  that  would  leave  nothyng  for  others,  men  that  would 
be  alone  on  the  earth,  men  that  bee  never  satisfied."  21  Its 
essence  was  an  attempt  to  extend  legal  rights,  while  repu- 
diating legal  and  quasi-legal  obligations.  It  was  against  this 
new  idolatry  of  irresponsible  ownership,  a  growing,  but  not 
yet  triumphant,  creed,  that  the  divines  of  the  Reformation 
called  down  fire  from  heaven. 

Their  doctrine  was  derived  from  the  conception  of  prop- 
erty, of  which  the  most  elaborate  formulation  had  been  made 
by  the  Schoolmen,  and  which,  while  justifying  it  on  grounds 
of  experience  and  expediency,  insisted  that  its  use  was  lim 
ited  at  every  turn  by  the  rights  of  the  community  and  the 
obligations  of  charity.  Its  practical  application  was  an  ideal- 
ized version  of  the  feudal  order,  which  was  vanishing  before 
the  advance  of  more  business-like  and  impersonal  forms  of 
land-ownership,  and  which,  once  an  engine  of  exploitation^ 
was  now  hailed  as  a  bulwark  to  protect  the  weak  against 
the  downward  thrust  of  competition.  Society  is  a  hierarchy 
of  rights  and  duties.  Law  exists  to  enforce  the  second,  as 
much  as  to  protect  the  first.  Property  is  not  a  mere  aggre- 
gate of  economic  privileges,  but  a  responsible  office.  It$ 
raison  d'etre  is  not  only  income,  but  service.  It  is  to  secure 
its  owner  such  means,  and  no  more  than  such  means,  as 


128  THE   CHURCH   OF   ENGLAND 

may  enable  him  to  perform  those  duties,  whether  labor  on 
the  land,  or  labor  in  government,  which  are  involved  in  the 
particular  status  which  he  holds  in  the  system.  He  who 
seeks  more  robs  his  superiors,  or  his  dependents,  or  both. 
He  who  exploits  his  property  with  a  single  eye  to  its  eco 
nomic  possibilities  at  once  perverts  its  very  essence  and 
destroys  his  own  moral  title,  for  he  has  "every  man's  living 
and  does  no  man's  duty."  22 

The  owner  is  a  trustee,  whose  rights  are  derived  from  the 
function  which  he  performs  and  should  lapse  if  he  repudiates 
it.  They  are  limited  by  his  duty  to  the  State;  they  are  lim- 
ited no  less  by  the  rights  of  his  tenants  against  him.  Just 
as  the  peasant  may  not  cultivate  his  land  in  the  way  whicb 
he  may  think  most  profitable  to  himself,  but  is  bound  by 
the  law  of  the  village  to  grow  the  crops  which  the  village 
needs  and  to  throw  his  strips  open  after  harvest  to  his  neigh- 
bors's  beasts,  so  the  lord  is  required  both  by  custom  and  by 
statute  to  forego  the  anti-social  profits  to  be  won  by  method's 
of  agriculture  which  injure  his  neighbors  and  weaken  the 
State.  He  may  not  raise  his  rent  or  demand  increased  lines, 
for  the  function  of  the  peasant,  though  different,  is  not  less 
essential  than  his  own  He  is,  in  short,  not  a  rentitr,  but  an 
officer,  and  it  is  for  the  Church  to  rebuke  him  when  he  sac- 
rifices the  duties  of  his  charge  to  the  greed  for  personal  gain. 
"We  heartily  pray  thee  to  send  thy  holy  spirit  into  the 
hearts  of  them  that  possess  the  grounds,  pastures,  and  dwell- 
ing-places of  the  earth,  that  they,  remembering  themselves 
to  be  thy  tenants,  may  not  rack  and  stretch  out  the  rents 
of  their  houses  and  lands,  nor  yet  take  unreasonable  fines 
and  incomes,  after  the  manner  of  covetous  worldlings  .  . 
but  so  behave  themselves  in  letting  out  their  tenements, 
lands  and  pastures,  that  after  this  life  they  may  be  received 
into  everlasting  dwelling  places."  23  Thus,  while  the  covetous 
worldlings  disposed  the  goods  of  this  transitory  life  to  their 
liking,  did  a  pious  monarch  consider  their  eternal  welfare 
in  the  Book  of  Private  Prayer  issued  in  1553. 

II.    RELIGIOUS  THEORY  AND  SOCIAL  POLICY 

If  a  philosophy  ol  society  is  to  be  effective,  it  must  be  as 
mobile  and  realistic  as  the  forces  which  it  would  control. 
The  weakness  of  an  attitude  which  met  the  onset  of  insur- 


RELIGIOUS  THEORY  AND  SOCIAL  POLICY  12$ 

gent  economic  interests  with  a  generalized  appeal  to  tradi- 
tional morality  and  an  idealization  of  the  past  was  only  too 
obvious.  Shocked,  confused,  thrown  on  to  a  helpless,  if 
courageous  aftdsaiaaaffit,  defensive  by  changes  even  in  the 
slowly  moving  world  of  agriculture,  medieval  social  theory, 
to  which  the  most  representative  minds  of  the  English 
Church  still  clung,  found  itself  swept  off  its  feet  after  the 
middle  of  the  century  by  the  swift  rise  of  a  commercial 
civilization,  in  which  all  traditional  landmarks  seemed  one 
by  one  to  be  submerged.  The  issue  over  which  the  struggle 
between  the  new  economic  movements  of  the  age  and  the 
scheme  of  economic  ethics  expounded  by  churchmen  was 
most  definitely  joined,  and  continued  longest,  was  not,  as  the 
modern  reader  might  be  disposed  to  expect,  that  of  wages, 
but  that  of  credit,  money-lending  and  prices.  The  center  of 
the  controversy — the  mystery  of  iniquity  in  which  a  host  of 
minor  scandals  were  conveniently,  if  inaccurately  epitomize*} 
— was  the  problem  which  contemporaries  described  by  the 
word  usury. 

"Treasure  doth  then  advance  greatness,"  wrote  Bacon,  in 
words  characteristic  of  the  social  ideal  of  the  age,  "when 
the  wealth  of  the  subject  be  rather  in  many  hands  than 
few."  24VIn  spite  of  the  growing  concentration  of  property, 
Tudor  England  was  still,  to  use  a  convenient  modern  phase, 
a  Distributive  State.  It  was  a  community  in  which  the  own- 
ership of  land,  and  of  the  simple  tools  used  in  most  indufc- 
tries,  was  not  the  badge  of  a  class,  but  the  attribute  of  a 
society,  and  in  which  the  typical  worker  was  a  peasant 
farmer,  a  tradesman,  or  a  small  master.  In  this  world  of 
small  property-owners,  of  whose  independence  and  prosper- 
ity English  publicists  boasted,  in  contrast  with  the  "housed 
beggars"  of  France  and  Germany,  the  wage-earners  were  a 
minority  scattered  in  the  interstices  of  village  and  borough, 
and,  being  normally  themselves  the  sons  of  peasants,  with 
the  prospect  of  stepping  into  a  holding  of  their  own,  or,  at 
worst,  the  chance  of  squatting  on  the  waste,  were  often  in  a 
strong  position  vis-a-vis  their  employers.  The  special  eco- 
nomic malaise  of  an  age  is  naturally  the  obverse  of  its  spe* 
cial  qualities.  Except  in  certain  branches  of  the  textile  in- 
dustry, the  grievance  which  supplied  fuel  to  social  agitation! 
which  evoked  programs  of  social  reform,  and  which  prompt- 
ed both  legislation  and  administrative  activity,  sprang,  not 


130  THE   CHURCH   OF   ENGLAND 

from  the  exploitation  of  a  wage-earning  proletariat  by  its 
employers,  but  from  the  relation  of  the  producer  to  the 
landlord  of  whom  he  held,  the  dealer  with  whom  he  bought 
and  sold,  and  the  local  capitalist,  often  the  dealer  in  another 
guise,  to  whom  he  ran  into  debt.  The  farmer  must  borrow 
money  when  the  season  is  bad,  or  merely  to  finance  the 
interval  between  sowing  and  harvest.  The  craftsman  must 
buy  raw  materials  on  credit  and  get  advances  before  his 
wares  are  sold.  The  young  tradesman  must  scrape  together 
a  little  capital  before  he  can  set  up  shop.  Even  the  cottager, 
who  buys  grain  at  the  local  market,  must  constantly  ask 
the  seller  to  "give  day."  Almost  every  one,  therefore,  at  one 
time  or  another,  has  need  of  the  money-lender.  And  the 
lender  is  often  a  monopolist — "a  money-master,"  a  malster 
or  corn  monger,  "a  rich  priest,"  who  is  the  solitary  capitalist 
in  a  community  of  peasants  and  artisans.  Naturally,  he  is 
apt  to  become  their  master.25 

In  such  circumstances  it  is  not  surprising  that  there  should 
have  been  a  popular  outcry  against  extortion  Inspired  by 
practical  grievances,  it  found  an  ally,  eloquent,  if  disarmed, 
in  the  teaching  of  the  Church.  The  doctrine  as  to  the  ethics 
of  economic  conduct,  which  had  been  formulated  by  medie- 
val Popes  and  interpreted  by  medieval  Schoolmen,  was  re- 
hearsed by  the  English  divines  of  the  sixteenth  century, 
not  merely  as  the  conventional  tribute  paid  by  a  formal  piety 
to  the  wisdom  of  the  past,  but  because  the  swift  changes  of 
the  period  in  commerce  and  agriculture  had,  not  softened, 
but  accentuated,  the  problems  of  conduct  for  which  it  had 
been  designed.  Nor  was  it  only  against  the  particular  case 
of  the  covetous  money-lender  that  the  preacher  and  the  mor- 
alist directed  their  arrows.  The  essence  of  the  medieval 
scheme  of  economic  ethics  had  been  its  insistence  on  equity 
in  bargaining — a  contract  is  fair,  St  Thomas  had  said,  when 
both  parties  gain  from  it  equally.  The  prohibition  of  usury 
had  been  the  kernel  of  its  doctrines,  not  because  the  gains 
of  the  money-lender  were  the  only  species,  but  because,  in 
the  economic  conditions  of  the  age,  they  were  the  most  con- 
spicuous species,  of  extortion. 

In  reality,  alike  in  the  Middle  Ages  and  in  the  sixteenth 
century,  the  word  usury  had  not  the  specialized  sense  which 
it  carries  today.  Like  the  modern  profiteer,  the  usurer  was  a 
character  so  unpopular  that  most  unpopular  characters  could 


RELIGIOUS   THEORY  AND  SOCIAL  POLICY  131 

be  called  usurers,  and  by  the  average  practical  man  almost 
any  form  of  bargain  which  he  thought  oppressive  would  b6 
classed  as  usurious.  The  interpretation  placed  on  the  word 
by  those  who  expounded  ecclesiastical  theories  of  usury  was 
equally  elastic.  Not  only  the  taking  of  interest  for  a  loan, 
but  the  raising  of  prices  by  a  monopolist,  the  beating  down 
of  prices  by  a  keen  bargainer,  the  rack-renting  of  land  by 
a  landlord,  the  sub-letting  of  land  by  a  tenant  at  a  rent 
higher  than  he  himself  paid,  the  cutting  of  wages  and  the 
paying  of  wages  in  truck,  the  refusal  of  discount  to  a  tardy 
debtor,  the  insistence  on  unreasonably  good  security  for  a 
loan,  the  excessive  profits  of  a  middleman — all  these  had 
been  denounced  as  usury  in  the  very  practical  thirteenth- 
century  manual  of  St.  Raymond;  26  all  these  were  among  the 
"unlawful  chaffer,"  the  "sublety  and  sleight,"  which  was 
what  the  plain  man  who  sat  on  juries  and  listened  to  ser- 
mons in  parish  churches  meant  by  usury  three  centuries 
later.  If  he  had  been  asked  why  usury  was  wrong,  he  would 
probably  have  answered  with  a  quotation  from  Scripture. 
If  he  had  been  asked  for  a  definition  of  usury,  he  would 
have  been  puzzled,  and  would  have  replied  in  the  words  of 
a  member  of  Parliament  who  spoke  on  the  bill  introduced 
in  1571:  "It  standeth  doubtful  what  usury  is;  we  have  nc 
true  definition  of  it."  *7  The  truth  is,  indeed,  that  any  bar- 
gain, in  which  one  party  obviously  gained  more  advantage 
than  the  other,  and  used  his  power  to  the  full,  was  regarded 
as  usurious.  The  description  which  best  sums  up  alike  pop- 
ular sentiment  and  ecclesiastical  teaching  is  contained  in 
the  comprehensive  indictment  applied  by  his  parishioners 
to  an  unpopular  divine  who  lent  at  a  penny  in  the  shilling — 
the  cry  of  all  poor  men  since  the  world  began — Dr.  Bennet 
uis  a  great  taker  of  advantages."  28 

It  was  the  fact  that  the  theory  of  usury  which  the  divines 
of  the  sixteenth  century  inherited  was  not  an  isolated  freak 
of  casuistical  ingenuity,  but  one  subordinate  element  in  a 
comprehensive  system  of  social  philosophy,  which  gave  its 
poignancy  to  the  controversy  of  which  it  became  the  center. 
The  passion  which  fed  on  its  dusty  dialectics  was  fanned 
by  the  conviction  that  the  issue  at  stake  was  not  merely  a 
legal  technicality.  It  was  the  fate  of  the  whole  scheme  of 
medieval  thought,  which  had  attempted  to  treat  economic 


132  THE  CHURCH  OF  ENGLAND 

affairs  as  part  of  a  hierarchy  of  values,  embracing  all  inter- 
ests and  activities,  of  which  the  apex  was  religion. 

If  the  Reformation  was  a  revolution,  it  was  a  revolution 
which  left  almost  intact  both  the  lower  ranges  of  ecclesiasti- 
cal organization  and  the  traditional  scheme  of  social  thought. 
The  villager  who,  resisting  the  temptations  of  the  alehouse, 
morris  dancing  or  cards,  attended  his  parish  church  from 
1530  to  1560,  must  have  been  bewildered  by  a  succession 
of  changes  in  the  appearance  of  the  building  and  the  form 
of  the  services.  But  there  was  little  to  make  him  conscious 
of  any  alteration  in  the  social  system  of  which  the  church 
was  the  center,  or  in  the  duties  which  that  system  imposed 
upon  himself.  After,  as  before,  the  Reformation,  the  parish 
continued  to  be  a  community  in  which  religious  and  social 
obligations  were  inextricably  intertwined,  and  it  was  as  a 
parishioner,  rather  than  as  a  subject  of  the  secular  authority, 
that  he  bore  his  share  of  public  burdens  and  performed  such 
public  functions  as  fell  to  his  lot.  The  officers  of  whom  he 
saw  most  in  the  routine  of  his  daily  life  were  the  church* 
wardens.  The  place  where  most  public  business  was  trans- 
acted, and  where  news  of  the  doings  of  the  great  world  came 
to  him,  was  the  parish  church.  The  contributions  levied 
from  him  were  demanded  in  the  name  of  the  parish.  Such 
education  as  was  available  for  his  children  was  often  given 
by  the  curate  or  parish  schoolmaster.  Such  training  in  co- 
operation with  his  fellows  as  he  received  sprang  from  com- 
mon undertakings  maintained  by  the  parish,  which  owned 
property,  received  bequests,  let  out  sheep  and  cattle,  ad- 
vanced money,  made  large  profits  by  church  sales,  and  occa- 
sionally engaged  in  trade.29  Membership  of  the  Church  and 
of  the  State  being  co-extensive  and  equally  compulsory,  the 
Government  used  the  ecclesiastical  organization  of  the  par- 
ish for  purposes  which,  in  a  later  age,  when  the  religious, 
political  and  economic  aspects  of  life  were  disentangled, 
were  to  be  regarded  as  secular.  The  pulpit  was  the  channel 
through  which  official  information  was  conveyed  to  the  pub- 
lic and  the  duty  of  obedience  inculcated.  It  was  to  the  clergy 
and  the  parochial  organization  that  the  State  turned  in 
coping  with  pauperism,  and  down  to  1597  collectors  for  the 
poor  were  chosen  by  the  churchwardens  in  conjunction  with 
the  parson. 

Where  questions  of  social  ethics  were  concerned,  the  re- 


RELIGIOUS   THEORY  AND  SOCIAL  POLICY  133 

ligious  thought  of  the  age  was  not  less  conservative  than  its 
ecclesiastical  organization.  But  in  their  view  of  religion  as 
embracing  all  sides  of  life,  and  in  their  theory  of  the  par- 
ticular social  obligations  which  religion  involved,  the  most 
representative  thinkers  of  the  Church  of  England  had  no 
intention  of  breaking  with  traditional  doctrines.  In  the  rooted 
suspicion  of  economic  motives  which  caused  them  to  damn 
each  fresh  manifestation  of  the  spirit  of  economic  enterprise 
as  a  new  form  of  the  sin  of  covetousness,  as  in  their  insist- 
ence that  the  criteria  of  economic  relations  and  of  the  social 
order  were  to  be  sought,  not  in  practical  expediency,  but 
in  truths  of  which  the  Church  was  the  guardian  and  the 
exponent,  the  utterances  of  men  of  religion,  in  the  reign 
of  Elizabeth,  in  spite  of  the  revolution  which  had  in- 
tervened, had  more  affinity  with  the  doctrines  of  the  School- 
men than  with  those  which  were  to  be  fashionable  after  the 
Restoration. 

The  oppressions  of  the  tyrannous  landlord,  who  used  bis 
economic  power  to  drive  an  unmerciful  bargain,  were  the 
subject  of  constant  denunciation  down  to  the  Civil  War. 
The  exactions  of  middlemen — "merchants  of  mischief  .  .  . 
[who]  do  make  all  things  dear  to  the  buyers,  and  yet  won- 
derful vile  and  of  small  price  to  many  that  must  needs  set 
or  sell  that  which  is  their  own  honestly  come  by" — were 
pilloried  by  Lever. J0  Nicholas  Heming,  whose  treatise  on 
The  Lawful  Use  of  Riches  became  something  like  a  stand- 
ard work,  expounded  the  doctrine  of  the  just  price,  and 
swept  impatiently  aside  the  argument  which  pleaded  free- 
dom of  contract  as  an  excuse  for  covetousness:  "Cloake  the 
same  by  what  title  you  liste,  your  synne  is  excedyng  greate. 
...  He  which  hurteth  but  one  man  is  in  a  damnable  case; 
what  shall  bee  thought  of  thee,  which  bryngest  whole 
householdes  to  th^ir  graves,  or  at  the  leaste  art  a  meanes 
of  their  extreame  miserie?  Thou  maiest  finde  shiftes  to 
avoide  the  danger  of  men,  but  assuredly  thou  shalte  not 
escape  the  judgemente  of  God." 31  Men  eminent  among 
Anglican  divines,  such  as  Sandys  and  Jewel,  took  part  in 
the  controversy  on  the  subject  of  usury.  A  bishop  of  Salis- 
bury gave  his  blessing  to  the  book  of  Wilson;  an  archbishop 
of  Canterbury  allowed  Mosse's  sharp  Arraignment  to  be 
dedicated  to  himself;  and  a  clerical  pamphleteer  in  the 
seventeenth  century  produced  a  catalogue  of  six  bishops 


THE  CHURCH  OF  ENGLAND 

and  ten  doctors  of  divinity — not  to  mention  numberless 
humbler  clergy — who  had  written  in  the  course  of  the  last 
hundred  years  on  different  aspects  of  the  sin  of  extortion 
in  all  its  manifold  varieties.82  The1  subject  was  still  a  favor- 
ite of  the  ecclesiastical  orator. The  sixteenth-century  preacher 
was  untrammeled  by  the  convention  which  in  a  more 
fastidious  age  was  to  preclude  as  an  impropriety  the  dis- 
cussion in  the  pulpit  of  the  problems  of  the  market-place. 
"As  it  belongeth  to  the  magistrate  to  punishe,"  wrote 
Heming,  "so  it  is  the  parte  of  the  preachers  to  reprove 
usurie.  .  .  .  First,  they  should  earnestly  inveigh  against 
all  unlawful  and  wicked  contractes.  .  .  .  Let  them  .  .  . 
amend  all  manifest  errours  in  bargaining  by  ecclesiasticall 
discipline  .  .  .  Then,  if  they  cannot  reforme  all  abuses 
which  they  shall  finde  in  bargaines,  let  them  take  heede  that 
they  trouble  not  the  Churche  overmuche,  but  commende  the 
cause  unto  God  .  .  .  Last  of  all,  let  them  with  diligence 
admonishe  the  ritche  men,  that  they  suffer  not  themselves 
to  be  entangled  with  the  shewe  of  ritches."  S3 

"This,"  wrote  an  Anglican  divine  in  reference  to  the  ec- 
clesiastical condemnation  of  usury,  "hath  been  the  generall 
judgment  of  the  Church  for  above  this  fifteene  hundred 
yeeres,  without  opposition,  in  this  point.  Poor  sillie  Church 
of  Christ,  that  could  never  finde  a  lawfull  usurie  before  this 
golden  age  wherein  we  live."  a4  The  first  fact  which  strikes 
the  modern  student  of  this  body  of  teaching  is  its  continuity 
with  the  past.  In  its  insistence  that  buying  and  selling,  let- 
ting and  hiring,  lending  and  borrowing,  are  to  be  controlled 
by  a  moral  law,  of  which  the  Church  is  the  guardian,  reli- 
gious opinion  after  the  Reformation  did  not  differ  from 
religious  opinion  before  it.  The  reformers  themselves  were 
conscious,  neither  of  the  emancipation  from  the  economic 
follies  of  the  age  of  medieval  darkness  ascribed  to  them  in 
the  eighteenth  century,  nor  of  the  repudiation  of  the  tradi- 
tional economic  morality  of  Christendom,  which  some  writ- 
ers have  held  to  have  been  the  result  of  the  revolt  from 
Rome.  The  relation  in  which  they  conceived  themselves  to 
stand  to  the  social  theory  of  the  medieval  Church  is  shown 
by  the  authorities  to  whom  they  appealed.  "Therefore  I 
would  not,"  wrote  Dr.  Thomas  Wilson,  Master  of  Requests 
and  for  a  short  time  Secretary  of  State,  "have  men  alto- 
gether to  be  enemies  to  the  canon  lawe,  and  to  condempne 


RELIGIOUS   THEORY  AND   SOCIAL   POLICY  135 

every  thinge  there  written,  because  the  Popes  were  aucthours 
of  them,  as  though  no  good  lawe  could  bee  made  by 
them.  .  .  .  Nay,  I  will  saye  playnely,  that  there  are  some 
suche  lawes  made  by  the  Popes  as  be  righte  godly,  saye 
others  what  they  list."  J5  From  the  lips  of  a  Tudor  official, 
such  sentiments  fell,  perhaps  with  a  certain  piquancy.  But, 
in  their  appeal  to  the  traditional  teaching  of  the  Church, 
Wilson's  words  represented  the  starting  point  from  which 
the  discussions  of  social  questions  still  commonly  set  out. 
The  Bible,  the  Fathers  and  the  Schoolmen,  the  decretals, 
church  councils,  and  commentators  on  the  canon  law — all 
these,  and  not  only  the  first,  continued  to  be  quoted  as  de- 
cisive on  questions  of  economic  ethics  by  men  to  whom  the 
theology  and  government  of  the  medieval  Church  were  an 
abomination.  What  use  Wilson  made  of  them,  a  glance  at 
his  book  will  show.  The  writer  who,  after  him,  produced 
the  most  elaborate  discussion  of  usury  in  the  latter  part  of 
the  century  prefaced  his  work  with  a  list  of  pre-Reforma- 
tion  authorities  running  into  several  pages.36  The  author  of 
a  practical  memorandum  on  the  amendment  of  the  law  with 
regard  to  money-lending — a  memorandum  which  appears  to 
have  had  some  effect  upon  policy — thought  it  necessary  to 
drag  into  a  paper  concerned  with  the  chicanery  of  financiers 
and  the  depreciation  of  sterling  by  speculative  exchange  busi- 
ness, not  only  Melanchthon,  but  Aquinas  and  Hostiensis.87, 
Even  a  moralist  who  denied  all  virtue  whatever  to  "the  de- 
crees of  the  Pope"  did  so  only  the  more  strongly  to  empha- 
size the  prohibition  of  uncharitable  dealing  contained  in  the 
"statutes  of  holie  Synodes  and  sayings  of  godlie  Fathers, 
whiche  vehemently  forbid  usurie." 3h  Objective  economic 
science  was  developing  in  the  hands  of  the  experts  who 
wrote  on  agriculture,  trade,  and,  above  all,  on  currency  and 
the  foreign  exchanges.  But  the  divines,  if  they  read  such 
works  at  all,  waved  them  on  one  side  as  the  intrusion  of 
Mammon  into  the  fold  of  Christian  morality,  and  by  their 
obstinate  obscurantism  helped  to  prepare  an  intellectual 
nemesis,  which  was  to  discredit  their  fervent  rhetoric  as 
the  voice  of  a  musty  superstition.  For  one  who  examined 
present  economic  realities,  ten  rearranged  thrice-quoted 
quotations  from  tomes  of  past  economic  casuistry.  Sermon 
was  piled  upon  sermon,  and  treatise  upon  treatise.  The  as- 
sumption of  all  is  that  the  traditional  teaching  of  the  Church 


13$  THE   CHURCH  OF  ENGLAND 

as  to  social  ethics  is  as  binding  on  men's  consciences  after 
the  Reformation  as  it  had  been  before  it. 

Pamphlets  and  sermons  do  not  deal  either  with  sins  which 
no  one  commits  or  with  sins  that  every  one  commits,  and 
the  literary  evidence  is  not  to  be  dismissed  merely  as  pious 
rhetoric.  The  literary  evidence  does  not,  however,  stand 
alone.  Upon  the  immense  changes  made  by  the  Reformation 
in  the  political  and  social  position  of  the  Church  it  is  not 
necessary  to  enlarge.  It  became,  in  effect,  one  arm  of  the 
State;  excommunication,  long  discredited  by  abuse,  was  fast 
losing  what  little  terrors  it  still  retained;  a  clergy  three- 
quarters  of  whom,  as  a  result  of  the  enormous  transference 
of  ecclesiastical  property,  were  henceforward  presented  by 
lay  patrons,  were  not  likely  to  display  any  excessive  inde- 
pendence. But  the  canon  law  was  nationalized,  not  abolished; 
the  assumption  of  most  churchmen  throughout  the  sixteenth 
century  was  that  it  was  to  be  administered;  and  the  canon 
law  included  the  whole  body  of  legislation  as  to  equity  in 
contracts  which  had  been  inherited  from  the  Middle  Ages. 
True,  it  was  administered  no  longer  by  the  clergy  acting  as 
the:  agents  of  Rome,  but  by  civilians  acting  under  authority 
of  the  Crown.  True,  after  the  prohibition  of  the  study  of 
canon  law — after  the  estimable  Dr.  Layton  had  "set  Dunce 
in  Bocardo"  at  Oxford— it  languished  at  the  universities. 
True,  for  the  seven  years  from  1545  to  1552,  and  again, 
and  on  this  occasion  for  good,  after  1571,  parliamentary 
legislation  expressly  sanctioned  loans  at  interest,  provided 
that  it  did  not  exceed  a  statutory  maximum.  But  the  con- 
vulsion which  changed  the  source  of  canon  law  did  not,  as 
far  as  these  matters  are  concerned,  alter  its  scope.  Its  valid- 
ity was  not  the  less  because  it  was  now  enforced  in  the 
name,  not  of  the  Pope,  but  of  the  King. 

As  Maitland  has  pointed  out,39  there  was  a  moment 
towards  the  middle  of  the  century  when  the  civil  law  was 
pressing  the  common  law  hard.  The  civil  law,  as  Sir  Thomas 
Smith  assured  the  yet  briefless  barrister,  offered  a  promising 
career,  since  it  was  practiced  in  the  ecclesiastical  courts.40 
Though  it  did  not  itself  forbid  usury,  it  had  much  to  say 
about  it;  it  was  a  doctor  of  the  civil  law  under  Elizabeth 
by  whom  the  most  elaborate  treatise  on  the  subject  was 
compiled.41  By  an  argument  made  familiar  by  a  modern 
controversy  on  which  lay  and  ecclesiastical  opinion  have 


RELIGIOUS   THEORY  AND   SOCIAL  POLICY  137 

diverged,  it  is  argued  that  the  laxity  of  the  State  does  not 
excuse  the  consciences  of  men  who  are  the  subjects,  not 
only  of  the  State,  but  of  the  Church.  "The  permission  of 
the  Prince,"  it  was  urged,  uis  no  absolution  from  the  au- 
thority of  the  Church.  Supposing  usury  to  be  unlawful  .  .  . 
yet  the  civil  laws  permit  it,  and  the  Church  forbids  it.  In 
this  case  the  Canons  are  to  be  preferred.  ...  By  the  laws 
no  man  is  compelled  to  be  an  usurer;  and  therefore  he  must 
pay  that  reverence  and  obedience  which  is  otherwise  due  to 
them  that  have  the  rule  over  them  in  the  conduct  of  their 
souls.7' 4- 

It  was  this  theory  which  was  held  by  almost  all  the  ec- 
clesiastical writers  who  dealt  with  economic  ethics  in  the 
sixteenth  century.  Their  view  was  that,  in  the  words  of  a 
pamphleteer,  "by  the  laws  of  the  Church  of  England  .  .  . 
usury  is  simply  and  generally  prohibited." 43  When  the 
lower  House  of  Convocation  petitioned  the  bishops  in  1554 
for  a  restoration  of  their  priviliges,  they  urged,  among  other 
matters,  that  " usurers  may  be  punished  by  the  canon  lawes 
as  in  tymes  past  has  been  used."44  In  the  abortive  scheme 
for  the  reorganization  of  the  ecclesiastical  jurisdiction  drawn 
up  by  Cranrner  and  Foxe,  usury  was  included  in  the  list  of 
offenses  with  which  the  ecclesiastical  courts  were  to  deal, 
and,  for  the  guidance  of  judges  in  what  must  often  have 
been  somewhat  knotty  cases,  a  note  was  added,  explaining 
that  it  was  not  to  be  taken  as  including  the  profits  derived 
from  objects  which  yielded  increase  by  the  natural  process 
of  growth. Jr'  Archbishop  Grindal's  injunctions  to  the  laity 
of  the  province  of  York  (1571)  expressly  emphasized  the 
duty  of  presenting  to  the  Ordinary  those  who  lend  and 
demand  back  more  than  the  principal,  whatever  the  guise 
under  which  the  transaction  may  be  concealed.40  Bishops' 
articles  of  visitation  down  to  the  Civil  War  required  the 
presentation  of  uncharitable  persons  and  usurers,  together 
with  drunkards,  ribalds,  swearers  and  sorcerers.47  The  rules 
to  be  observed  in  excommunicating  the  impenitent  promul- 
gated in  1585,  the  Canons  of  the  Province  of  Canterbury 
in  1604,  and  of  the  Irish  Church  in  1634,  all  included  a  pro- 
vision that  the  usurer  should  be  subjected  to  ecclesiastical 
discipline.48 

The  activity  of  the  ecclesiastical  courts  had  not  ceased 
with  the  Reformation,  and  they  continued  throughout  the 


138  THE  CHURCH  OF  ENGLAND 

last  half  of  the  century  to  play  an  important,  if  increasingly 
unpopular,  part  in  the  machinery  of  local  government.  In  ad- 
dition to  enforcing  the  elementary  social  obligation  of  char- 
ity, by  punishing  the  man  who  refused  to  "pay  to  the  poor 
men's  box,"  or  who  was  "detected  for  being  an  uncharitable 
person  and  for  not  giving  to  the  poor  and  impotent,"  49  they 
dealt  also,  at  least  in  theory,  with  those  who  offended  against 
Christian  morality  by  acts  of  extortion.  The  jurisdiction  of 
the  Church  in  these  matters  was  expressly  reserved  by  legis- 
lation, and  ecclesiastical  lawyers,  while  lamenting  the  en- 
croachments of  the  common  law  courts,  continued  to  claim 
certain  economic  misdemeanors  as  their  province.  That,  in 
spite  of  the  rising  tide  of  opposition,  the  references  to  ques- 
tions of  this  kind  in  articles  of  visitation  were  not  wholly  an 
affair  of  common  form,  is  suggested  by  the  protests  against 
the  interference  of  the  clergy  in  matters  of  business,  and  by 
the  occasional  cases  which  show  that  commercial  transactions 
'Continued  to  be  brought  before  the  ecclesiastical  courts.  The 
typical  usurer  was  apt,  indeed,  to  outrage  not  one,  but  all,  of 
the  decencies  of  social  intercourse.  "Thomas  Wilkoxe,"  com- 
plained his  fellow  burgesses,  "is  excommunicated,  and  dis- 
quieteth  the  parish  in  the  time  of  divine  service.  He  is  a  hor- 
rible usurer,  taking  Id.  and  sometimes  2d.  for  a  shilling  by 
the  week.  He  had  been  cursed  by  his  own  father  and  mother. 
For  the  space  of  two  years  he  hath  not  received  the  Holy 
Communion,  but  every  Sunday,  when  the  priest  is  ready  to 
go  to  the  Communion,  then  he  departeth  the  church  for  the 
receiving  of  his  weekly  usury,  and  doth  not  tarry  the  end  of 
divine  service  thrice  in  the  year."  50  Whether  the  archdeacon 
corrected  a  scandal  so  obviously  suitable  for  ecclesiastical 
discipline,  we  do  not  know.  But  in  1578  a  case  of  clerical 
usury  is  heard  in  the  court  of  the  archdeacon  of  Essex.51 
Twenty-two  years  later,  a  usurer  is  presented  with  other  of- 
fenders on  the  occasion  of  the  visitation  of  some  Yorkshire 
parishes.52  Even  in  1619  two  instances  occur  in  which  money- 
lenders are  cited  before  the  Court  of  the  Commissary  of  the 
Bishop  of  London,  on  the  charge  of  "lending  upon  pawnes 
for  an  excessive  gain  commonly  reported  and  cried  out  of." 
One  is  excommunicated  and  afterwards  absolved;  both  are 
admonished  to  amend  their  ways.53 

There  is  no  reason,  however,  to  suppose  that  such  cases 
were  other  than  highly  exceptional;  nor  is  it  from  the  occa- 


RELIGIOUS  THEORY  AND   SOCIAL  POLICY  139 

sional  activities  of  the  ever  more  discredited  ecclesiastical  ju- 
risdiction that  light  on  the  practical  application  of  the  ideas 
of  the  age  as  to  social  ethics  is  to  be  sought.  Ecclesiastical 
discipline  is  at  all  times  but  a  misleading  clue  to  the  influ- 
ence of  religious  opinion,  and  on  the  practice  of  a  time  when, 
except  for  the  Court  of  High  Commission,  the  whole  system 
was  in  decay,  the  scanty  proceedings  of  the  courts  Christian 
throw  little  light.  To  judge  the  degree  to  which  the  doctrines 
expounded  by  divines  were  accepted  or  repudiated  by  the 
common  sense  of  the  laity,  one  must  turn  to  the  records 
which  show  how  questions  of  business  ethics  were  handled 
by  individuals,  by  municipal  bodies  and  by  the  Government. 
The  opinion  of  the  practical  man  on  questions  of  eco- 
nomic conduct  was  in  the  sixteenth  century  in  a  condition  of 
even  more  than  its  customary  confusion.  A  century  before, 
he  had  practised  extortion  and  been  told  that  it  was  wrong; 
for  it  was  contrary  to  the  law  of  God.  A  century  later,  he  was 
to  practise  it  and  be  told  that  he  was  right;  for  it  was  in 
accordance  with  the  law  of  nature.  In  this  matter,  as  in  oth- 
ers of  even  greater  moment,  the  two  generations  which  fol- 
lowed the  Reformation  were  unblessed  by  these  ample  certi- 
tudes. They  walked  in  an  obscurity  where  the  glittering  ar- 
mor of  theologians 

made 
A  little  glooming  light,  most  like  a  shade. 

In  practice,  since  new  class  interests  and  novel  ideas  had 
arisen,  but  had  not  yet  wholly  submerged  those  which  pre- 
ceded them,  every  shade  of  opinion,  from  that  of  the  pious 
burgess,  who  protested  indignantly  against  being  saddled  with 
a  vicar  who  took  a  penny  in  the  shilling,  to  the  latitudinari- 
anism  of  the  cosmopolitan  financier,  to  whom  the  confusion 
of  business  with  morals  was  a  vulgar  delusion,  was  repre- 
sented in  the  economic  ethics  of  Elizabethan  England. 

As  far  as  the  smaller  property-owners  were  concerned,  the 
sentiment  of  laymen  differed,  on  the  whole,  less  widely  from 
the  doctrines  expounded  by  divines,  than  it  did  from  the  in- 
dividualism which  was  beginning  to  carry  all  before  it  among 
the  leaders  of  the  world  of  business.  Against  the  rising  finan- 
cial interests  of  the  day  were  arrayed  the  stolid  conservatism 
of  the  peasantry  and  the  humble  bourgeoisie,  whose 


140  THE   CHURCH   OF  ENGLAND 

ception  of  social  expediency  was  the  defense  of  customary 
relations  against  innovation,  and  who  regarded  the  growth  of 
this  new  power  with  something  of  the  same  jealous  hostility 
as  they  opposed  to  the  economic  radicalism  of  the  enclosing 
landlord.  At  bottom,  it  was  an  instinctive  movement  of  self- 
protection.  Free  play  for  the  capitalist  seemed  to  menace  the 
independence  of  the  small  producer,  who  tilled  the  nation's 
fields  and  wove  its  cloth.  The  path  down  which  the  financier 
beguiles  his  victims  may  seem  at  first  to  be  strewn  with  roses; 
but  at  the  end  of  it  lies — incredible  nightmare — a  regime  of 
universal  capitalism,  in  which  peasant  and  small  master  will 
have  been  merged  in  a  property-less  proletariat,  and  "the 
riches  of  the  city  of  London,  and  in  effect  of  all  this  realm, 
shall  be  at  that  time  in  the  hands  of  a  few  men  having  un- 
merciful hearts  "  r'4 

Against  the  landlord  who  enclosed  commons,  converted 
arable  to  pasture,  and  rack-rented  his  tenants,  local  resent- 
ment, unless  supported  by  the  Government,  was  powerless 
Against  the  engrosser,  however,  it  mobilized  the  traditional 
machinery  of  maximum  prices  and  market  regulations,  and 
dealt  with  the  usurer  as  best  it  could,  by  presenting  him  be- 
fore the  justices  in  Quarter  Sessions,  by  advancing  money 
from  the  municipal  exchequer  to  assist  his  victims,  and  even, 
on  occasion,  by  establishing  a  public  pawnshop,  with  a  mo- 
nopoly of  the  right  to  make  loans,  as  a  protection  to  the  in- 
habitants against  extreme  "usurers  and  extortioners  "  The 
commonest  chanty  of  the  age,  which  was  the  establishment 
of  a  fund  to  make  advances  without  interest  to  tradesmen, 
was  inspired  by  similar  motives.  Its  aim  was  to  enable  the 
youne:  artisan  or  shopkeeper,  the  favorite  victim  of  the 
money-lender,  to  acquire  the  indispensable  "stock,'1  without 
which  he  could  not  set  up  in  business  r'r> 

The  issues  which  confronted  the  Government  were  natur- 
ally more  complicated,  and  its  attitude  was  more  ambiguous. 
The  pressure  of  commercial  interests  growing  in  wealth  and 
influence,  its  own  clamorous  financial  necessities,  the  mere 
logic  of  economic  development,  made  it  out  of  the  question 
for  it  to  contemplate,  even  if  it  had  been  disposed  to  do  so, 
the  rigorous  economic  discipline  desired  by  the  divines.  Tra- 
dition, a  natural  conservatism,  the  apprehension  of  public 
disorder  caused  by  enclosures  or  by  distress  among  the  in- 
dustrial population,  a  belief  in  its  own  mission  as  the  guar- 


RELIGIOUS  THEORY  AND  SOCIAL  POLICY  14} 

dian  of  "good  order"  in  trade,  not  unmingled  with  a  hope 
that  the  control  of  economic  affairs  might  be  made  to  yield 
agreeable  financial  pickings,  gave  it  a  natural  bias  to  a  policy 
which  aimed  at  drawing  all  the  threads  of  economic  life  into 
the  hands  of  a  paternal  monarchy. 

In  the  form  which  the  system  assumed  under  Elizabeth, 
considerations  of  public  policy,  which  appealed  to  the  State, 
were  hardly  distinguishable  from  considerations  of  social 
morality,  which  appealed  to  the  Church.  As  a  result  of  the 
Reformation  the  relations  previously  existing  between  the 
Church  and  the  State  had  been  almost  exactly  reversed.  In 
the  Middle  Ages  the  former  had  been,  at  least  in  theory,  the 
ultimate  authority  on  questions  of  public  and  private  moral- 
ity, while  the  latter  was  the  police-officer  which  enforced  its 
decrees.  In  the  sixteenth  century,  the  Church  became  the 
ecclesiastical  department  of  the  State,  and  religion  was  used 
to  lend  a  moral  sanction  to  secular  social  policy.  But  the  re- 
ligious revolution  had  not  destroyed  the  conception  of  a  sin- 
gle society,  of  which  Church  and  State  were  different  as- 
pects; and,  when  the  canon  law  became  "the  King's  ecclesi- 
astical law  of  England,'*  the  jurisdiction  of  both  inevitably 
tended  to  merge.  Absorbing  the  ecclesiastical  authority  into 
itself,  the  Crown  had  its  own  reason  of  political  expediency 
for  endeavoring  to  maintain  traditional  standards  of  social 
conduct,  as  an  antidote  for  what  Cecil  called  "the  license 
grown  by  liberty  of  the  Gospel."  Ecclesiastics,  in  their  turn, 
were  public  officers — under  Elizabeth  the  bishop  was  nor- 
mally also  a  justice  of  the  peace — and  relied  on  secular  ma- 
chinery to  enforce,  not  only  religious  conformity,  but  Chris- 
tian morality,  because  both  were  elements  in  a  society  in 
which  secular  and  spiritual  interests  had  not  yet  been  com- 
pletely disentangled  from  each  other.  "We  mean  by  the 
Commonwealth,"  wrote  Hoker,  "that  society  with  relation 
unto  all  public  affairs  thereof,  only  the  matter  of  true  religion 
accepted;  by  the  Church,  the  same  society,  with  only  refer- 
ence unto  the  matter  of  true  religion,  without  any  other 
affairs  besides."56 

In  economic  and  social,  as  in  ecclesiastical,  matters,  the 
opening  years  of  Elizabeth  were  a  period  of  conservative  re- 
construction. The  psychology  of  a  nation  which  lives  pre- 
dominantly by  the  land  is  in  sharp  contrast  with  that  of  a 
commercial  society.  In  the  latter,  when  all  goes  well,  contin- 


142  THE    CHUKCH   OF   ENGLAND 

uous  expansion  is  taken  for  granted  as  the  rule  of  life,  new 
horizons  are  constantly  opening,  and  the  catchword  of  pol- 
itics is  the  encouragement  of  enterprise  In  the  former,  the 
number  of  niches  into  which  each  successive  generation  must 
be  fitted  is  strictly  limited;  movement  means  disturbance, 
for,  as  one  man  rises,  another  is  thrust  down ;  and  the  object 
of  statesmen  is,  not  to  fester  individual  initiative,  but  to  pre- 
vent social  dislocation.  It  was  in  this  mood  that  Tudor  Privy 
Councils  approached  questions  of  social  policy  and  indus- 
trial organization.  Except  when  they  were  diverted  by  finan- 
cial interests,  or  lured  into  ambitious,  and  usually  unsuccess- 
ful, projects  for  promoting  economic  development,  their  ideal 
was,  not  progress,  but  stability.  Their  enemies  were  disorder, 
and  the  restless  appetites  which,  since  they  led  to  the  en- 
croachment of  class  on  class,  were  thought  to  provoke  it.  Dis- 
trusting economic  individualism  for  reasons  of  state  as  heart- 
ily as  did  churchmen  for  reasons  of  religion,  their  aim  was  to 
crystallize  existing  class  relationships  by  submitting  them  to 
the  pressure,  at  once  restrictive  and  protective,  of  a  paternal 
Government,  vigilant  to  detect  all  movements  which  men- 
aced the  established  order,  and  alert  to  suppress  them. 

Take  but  degree  away,  untune  that  string, 

And,  hark,  what  discord  follows ' 

Force  should  be  right,  or  rather,  right  and  wrong 

(Between  whose  endless  jar  justice  resides) 

Should  lose  their  names,  and  so  should  justice  too 

Then  every  thing  includes  itself  in  power, 

Power  into  will,  will  into  appetite; 

And  appetite,  an  universal  wolf, 

So  doubly  seconded  with  will  and  power, 

And,  last,  eat  up  himself 

In  spite  of  the  swift  expansion  of  commerce  in  the  latter 
part  of  the  century,  the  words  of  Ulysses  continued  for  long 
to  express  the  official  attitude. 

The  practical  application  of  such  conceptions  was  an  elab- 
orate system  of  what  might  be  called,  to  use  a  modern  anal- 
ogy, "controls."  Wages,  the  movement  of  labor,  the  entry 
into  a  trade,  dealings  in  grain  and  in  wool,  methods  of  cul- 
tivation, methods  of  manufacture,  foreign  exchange  business, 
rates  of  interest — all  are  controlled,  partly  by  Statute,  but 
still  more  by  the  administrative  activity  of  the  Council.  In 
theory,  nothing  is  too  small  or  too  great  to  escape  the 


RELIGIOUS  THEORY  AND  SOCIAL  POLICY  14J 

eyes  of  an  omniscient  State.  Does  a  landowner  take  advan* 
tage  of  the  ignorance  of  peasants  and  the  uncertainty  of  the 
law  to  enclose  commons  or  evict  copyholders?  The  Council, 
while  protesting  that  it  does  not  intend  to  hinder  him  from 
asserting  his  rights  at  common  law,  will  intervene  to  stop 
gross  cases  of  oppression,  to  prevent  poor  men  from  being 
made  the  victims  of  legal  chicanery  and  intimidation,  to  set- 
tle disputes  by  common  sense  and  moral  pressure,  to  remind 
the  aggressor  that  he  is  bound  "rather  to  consider  what  is 
agreeable  ...  to  the  use  of  this  State  and  for  the  good  of  the 
comon  wealthe,  than  to  seeke  the  uttermost  advantage  that 
a  landlord  for  his  particular  profit  maie  take  amonge  his 
tenaunts."  57  Have  prices  been  raised  by  a  bad  harvest?  The 
Council  will  issue  a  solemn  denunciation  of  the  covetousness 
of  speculators,  "in  conditions  more  like  to  wolves  or  cormo- 
rants than  to  natural  men,"  58  who  take  advantage  of  the 
dearth  to  exploit  public  necessities;  will  instruct  the  Com- 
missioners of  Grain  and  Victuals  to  suspend  exports;  and  will 
order  justices  to  inspect  barns,  ration  supplies,  and  compel 
farmers  to  sell  surplus  stocks  at  a  fixed  price.  Does  the  col- 
lapse of  the  continental  market  threaten  distress  in  the  tex* 
tile  districts?  The  Council  will  put  pressure  on  clothiers  to 
find  work  for  the  operatives,  "this  being  the  rule  by  which 
the  wool-grower,  the  clothier  and  merchant  must  be  gov- 
erned, that  whosoever  had  a  part  of  the  gaine  in  profitable 
times  .  .  .  must  now,  in  the  decay  of  trade  .  .  .  beare  a  part 
of  the  publicke  losses,  as  may  best  conduce  to  the  good  of 
the  publicke  and  the  maintenance  of  the  generall  trade." 59 
Has  the  value  of  sterling  fallen  on  the  Antwerp  market?  The 
Council  will  consider  pegging  the  exchanges,  and  will  even 
attempt  to  nationalize  foreign  exchange  business  by  prohib- 
iting private  transactions  altogether.60  Are  local  authorities 
negligent  in  the  administration  of  the  Poor  Law?  The  Coun- 
cil, which  insists  on  regular  reports  as  to  the  punishment  of 
vagrants,  the  relief  of  the  impotent,  and  the  steps  taken  to 
provide  materials  on  which  to  employ  the  able-bodied,  inun- 
dates them  with  exhortations  to  mend  their  ways  and  with 
threats  of  severer  proceedings  if  they  fail.  Are  tradesmen  in 
difficulties?  The  Council,  which  keeps  sufficiently  in  touch 
with  business  conditions  to  know  when  the  difficulties  of 
borrowers  threaten  a  crisis,  endeavors  to  exercise  a  moderat- 
ing influence  by  making  an  example  of  persons  guilty  of  fla- 


144  THE    CHURCH   OF   ENGLAND 

grant  extortion,  or  by  inducing  the  parties  to  accept  a  com- 
promise. A  mortgagee  accused  of  "hard  and  unchristianty 
dealing"  is  ordered  to  restore  the  land  which  he  has  seized, 
or  to  appear  before  the  Council.  A  creditor  who  has  been 
similarly  "hard  and  unconscionable"  is  committed  to  the 
Fleet.  The  justices  of  Norfolk  are  instructed  to  put  pressure 
on  a  money-lender  who  has  taken  "very  unjust  and  immod- 
erate advantage  by  way  of  usury."  The  bishop  of  Exeter  is 
urged  to  induce  a  usurer  in  his  diocese  to  show  "a  more 
Christian  and  charitable  consideration  of  these  his  neigh- 
bors." A  nobleman  has  released  two  offenders  imprisoned  by 
the  High  Commission  for  the  Province  of  York  for  having 
"taken  usury  contrary  to  the  laws  of  God  and  of  the  realm/' 
and  is  ordered  at  once  to  recommit  them.  No  Government 
can  face  with  equanimity  a  state  of  things  in  which  large 
numbers  of  respectable  tradesmen  may  be  plunged  into  bank- 
ruptcy. In  times  of  unusual  depression,  the  Council's  inter- 
vention to  prevent  creditors  from  pressing  their  claims  to  the 
hilt  was  so  frequent  as  to  create  the  impression  of  something 
like  an  informal  moratorium.61 

The  Government  of  the  Tudors  and,  still  more,  of  the  first 
two  Stuarts,  were  masters  of  the  ast  of  disguising  common- 
place, and  sometimes  sordid,  motives  beneath  a  glittering 
facade  of  imposing  principles.  In  spite  of  its  lofty  declara- 
tions of  a  disinterested  solicitude  for  the  public  welfare,  the 
social  policy  of  the  monarchy  not  only  was  as  slipshod  in  ex- 
ecution as  it  was  grandiose  in  design,  but  was  not  seldom  per- 
verted into  measures  disastrous  to  its  ostensible  ends,  both 
by  the  sinister  pressure  of  sectional  interests,  and  by  the  in- 
sistent necessities  of  an  empty  exchequer.  Its  fundamental 
conception,  however — the  philosophy  of  the  thinkers  and  of 
the  few  statesmen  who  rose  above  immediate  exigencies  to 
consider  the  significance  of  the  system  in  its  totality — had 
a  natural  affinity  with  the  doctrines  which  commended  them- 
selves to  men  of  religion.  It  was  of  an  ordered  and  graded 
society,  in  which  each  class  performed  its  allotted  function, 
and  was  secured  such  a  livelihood,  and  no  more  than  such  a 
livelihood,  as  was  proportioned  to  its  status.  "God  and  the 
Kinge,"  wrote  one  who  had  labored  much,  amid  grave  per- 
sonal dangers,  for  the  welfare  of  his  fellows,  "hathe  not  sent 
us  the  poor  lyvinge  we  have,  but  to  doe  services  therfore 
amonge  our  neighbours  abroade."  *2  The  divines  who  fulmi- 


RELIGIOUS   THEORY   AND   SOCIAL   POLICY  145 

nated  against  the  uncharitable  covetousness  of  the  extortion- 
ate middleman,  the  grasping  money-lender,  or  the  tyrannous 
landlord,  saw  in  the  measures  by  which  the  Government 
endeavored  to  suppress  the  greed  of  individuals  or  the  col- 
lision of  classes  a  much  needed  cement  of  social  solidarity, 
and  appealed  to  Caesar  to  redouble  his  penalties  upon  an  eco- 
nomic license  which  was  hateful  to  God.  The  statesman  con- 
cerned to  prevent  agitation  saw  in  religion  the  preservative 
of  order,  and  the  antidote  for  the  cupidity  or  ambition  which 
threatened  to  destroy  it,  and  reenforced  the  threat  of  tem- 
poral penalties  with  arguments  that  would  not  have  been  out 
of  place  in  the  pulpit.  To  both  alike  religion  is  concerned 
with  something  more  than  personal  salvation.  It  is  the  sanc- 
tion of  social  duties  and  the  spiritual  manifestation  of  the 
corporate  life  of  a  complex,  yet  united,  society.  To  both  the 
State  is  something  more  than  an  institution  created  by  ma- 
terial necessities  or  political  convenience.  It  is  the  temporal 
expression  of  spiritual  obligations.  It  is  a  link  between  the  in- 
dividual soul  and  that  supernatural  society  of  which  all 
Christian  men  are  held  to  be  members  It  rests  not  merely 
on  practical  convenience,  but  on  the  will  of  God. 

Of  that  philosophy,  the  classical  expression,  at  once  the 
most  catholic,  the  most  reasonable  and  the  most  sublime,  is 
the  work  of  Hooker.  What  it  meant  to  one  cast  in  a  narrower 
mould,  pedantic,  irritable  and  intolerant,  yet  not  without  the 
streak  of  harsh  nobility  which  belongs  to  all  who  love  an  idea, 
however  unwisely,  more  than  their  own  ease,  is  revealed  in 
the  sermons  and  the  activity  of  Laud.  Laud's  intellectual  lim- 
itations and  practical  blunders  need  no  emphasis.  If  his  vices 
made  him  intolerable  to  the  most  powerful  forces  of  his  own 
age,  his  virtues  were  not  of  a  kind  to  commend  him  to  those 
of  its  successor,  and  history  has  been  hardly  more  merciful 
to  him  than  were  his  political  opponents.  But  an  intense  con- 
viction of  the  fundamental  solidarity  of  all  the  manifold 
elements  in  a  great  community,  a  grand  sense  of  the  dignity 
of  public  duties,  a  passionate  hatred  for  the  self-seeking  pet- 
tiness of  personal  cupidities  and  sectional  interests — these 
qualities  are  not  among  the  weaknesses  against  which  the 
human  nature  of  ordinary  men  requires  to  be  most  upon  its 
guard,  and  these  qualities  Laud  possessed,  not  only  in  abun- 
dance, but  to  excess.  His  worship  of  unity  was  an  idolatry, 
his  detestation  of  faction  a  superstition.  Church  and  State 


146  THE   CHURCH   OF   ENGLAND 

are  one  Jerusalem:  "Both  Commonwealth  and  Church  are 
collective  bodies,  made  up  of  many  into  one;  and  both  so 
near  allied  that  the  one,  the  Church,  can  never  subsist  but 
in  the  other,  the  Commonwealth;  nay,  so  near,  that  the  same 
men,  which  in  a  temporal  respect  make  the  Commonwealth, 
do  in  a  spiritual  make  the  Church."  63  Private  and  public  in- 
terests are  inextricably  interwoven.  The  sanction  of  unity  is 
religion.  The  foundation  of  unity  is  justice:  "God  will  not 
bless  the  State,  if  kings  and  magistrates  do  not  execute  judg- 
ment, if  the  widow  and  the  fatherless  have  cause  to  cry  out 
against  the  'thrones  of  justice/  "  °4 

To  a  temper  so  permeated  with  the  conception  that  society 
is  an  organism  compact  of  diverse  parts,  and  that  the  grand 
end  of  government  is  to  maintain  their  cooperation,  every 
social  movement  or  personal  motive  which  sets  group  against 
group,  or  individual  against  individual,  appears,  not  the  irre- 
pressible energy  of  life,  but  the  mutterings  of  chaos.  The 
first  demon  to  be  exorcised  is  party,  for  Governments  must 
"entertain  no  private  business,"  and  "parties  are  ever  private 
ends."  65  The  second  is  the  self-interest  which  leads  the  indi- 
vidual to  struggle  for  riches  and  advancement.  "There  is  no 
private  end,  but  in  something  or  other  it  will  be  led  to  run 
cross  the  public;  and,  if  gain  come  in,  though  it  be  by  'mak- 
ing shrines  for  Diana,'  it  is  no  matter  with  them  though 
Ephesus  be  in  an  uproar  for  it."  of*  For  Laud,  the  political 
virtues,  by  which  he  understands  subordination,  obedience, 
a  willingness  to  sacrifice  personal  interests  for  the  good  of 
the  community,  are  as  much  part  of  the  Christian's  religion 
as  are  the  duties  of  private  life;  and,  unlike  some  of  those 
who  sigh  for  social  unity  today,  he  is  as  ready  to  chastise  the 
rich  and  powerful,  who  thwart  the  attainment  of  that  ideal, 
as  he  is  to  preach  it  to  the  humble.  To  talk  of  holiness  and 
to  practice  injustice  is  mere  hypocrisy.  Man  is  born  a  mem- 
ber of  society  and  is  dedicated  by  religion  to  the  service  of 
his  fellows.  To  repudiate  the  obligation  is  to  be  guilty  of  a 
kind  of  political  atheism. 

"If  any  man  be  so  addicted  to  his  private,  that  he  neglect 
the  common,  state,  he  is  void  of  the  sense  of  piety  and  wish- 
eth  peace  and  happiness  to  himself  in  vain.  For  whoever  he 
be,  he  must  live  in  the  body  of  the  Commonwealth,  and  in 
the  body  of  the  Church."  °7  To  one  holding  such  a  creed  eco- 
nomic individualism  was  hardly  less  abhorrent  than  religious 


RELIGIOUS   THEORY   AND   SOCIAL  POLICY  147 

nonconformity,  and  its  repression  was  a  not  less  obvious 
duty;  for  both  seemed  incompatible  with  the  stability  of  a 
society  in  which  Commonwealth  and  Church  were  one.  It  is 
natural,  therefore,  that  Laud's  utterances  in  the  matter 
of  social  policy  should  have  shown  a  strong  bias  in  favor 
of  the  control  of  economic  relations  by  an  authoritarian 
State,  which  reached  its  climax  in  the  eleven  years  of 
personal  government.  It  was  a  moment  when,  partly  in 
continuance  of  the  traditional  policy  of  protecting  peas- 
ants and  maintaining  the  supply  of  grain,  partly  for  less 
reputable  reasons  of  finance,  the  Government  was  more  than 
usually  active  in  harrying  the  depopulating  landlord.  The 
Council  gave  sympathetic  consideration  to  petitions  from 
peasants  begging  for  protection  or  redress,  and  in  1630  di- 
rections were  issued  to  the  justices  of  five  midland  counties 
to  remove  all  enclosures  made  in  the  last  five  years,  on  the 
ground  that  they  resulted  in  depopulation  and  were  particu- 
larly harmful  in  times  of  dearth.  In  1632,  1635,  and  1636, 
three  Commissions  were  appointed  and  special  instructions 
against  enclosure  were  issued  to  the  Justices  of  Assize.  In 
parts  of  the  country,  at  any  rate,  land  which  had  been  laid 
down  to  grass  was  plowed  up  in  obedience  to  the  Govern- 
ment's orders  In  the  four  years  from  1635  to  1638  a  list  of 
some  600  offenders  was  returned  to  the  Council,  and  about 
/  50,000  was  imposed  upon  them  in  fines.68  With  this  policy 
Laud  was  whole-heartedly  in  sympathy.  A  letter  in  his  pri- 
vate correspondence,  in  which  he  expresses  his  detestation  of 
enclosure,  reveals  the  temper  which  evoked  Clarendon's  gen- 
tle complaint  that  the  archbishop  made  himself  unpopular 
by  his  inclination  ua  little  too  much  to  countenance  the  Com- 
mission for  Depopulation."  °9  Laud  was  himself  an  active 
member  of  the  Commission,  and  dismissed  with  impatient 
contempt  the  squirearchy's  appeal  to  the  common  law.  In  the 
day  of  his  ruin  he  was  reminded  by  his  enemies  of  the  need- 
lessly sharp  censures  with  which  he  barbed  the  fine  imposed 
upon  an  enclosing  landlord.70 

The  prevention  of  enclosure  and  depopulation  was  merely 
one  element  in  a  general  policy,  by  which  a  benevolent  Gov- 
ernment, unhampered  by  what  Laud  had  called  "that  noise" 
of  parliamentary  debate,  was  to  endeavor  by  even-handed 
pressure  to  enforce  social  obligations  on  great  and  small,  and 
to  prevent  the  public  interest  being  sacrificed  to  an  uncon- 


148  THE   CHURCH   OF   ENGLAND 

scionable  appetite  for  private  gain.  The  preoccupation  of  the 
Council  with  the  problem  of  securing  adequate  food  supplies 
and  reasonable  prices,  with  poor  relief,  and,  to  a  lesser  de- 
gree, with  questions  of  wages,  has  been  described  by  Miss 
Leonard,  and  its  attempts  to  protect  craftsmen  against  ex- 
ploitation at  the  hands  of  merchants  by  Professor  Unwin.71 
In  1630-1  it  issued  in  an  amended  form  the  Elizabethan 
Book  of  Orders,  instructing  justices  as  to  their  duty  to  see 
that  markets  were  served  and  prices  controlled,  appointed  a 
special  committee  of  the  Privy  Council  as  Commissioners  of 
the  Poor  and  later  a  separate  Commission,  and  issued  a  Book 
of  Orders  for  the  better  administration  of  the  Poor  Law.  In 
1629,  1631,  and  again  in  1637,  it  took  steps  to  secure  that 
the  wages  of  textile  workers  in  East  Anglia  were  raised,  and 
punished  with  imprisonment  L*  the  Fleet  an  employer  noto- 
rious for  paying  in  truck.  As  President  of  the  Council  of  the 
North,  Wentworth  protected  the  commoners  whose  vested 
interests  were  threatened  by  the  drainage  of  Hatfield  Chase, 
and  endeavored  to  insist  on  the  stricter  administration  of 
the  code  regulating  the  woollen  industry.72 

Such  action,  even  if  inspired  largely  by  the  obvious  inter- 
est of  the  Government,  which  had  enemies  enough  on  its 
hands  already,  in  preventing  popular  discontent,  was  of  a 
kind  to  appeal  to  one  with  Laud's  indifference  to  the  opinion 
of  the  wealthier  classes,  and  with  Laud's  belief  in  the  divine 
mission  of  the  House  of  David  to  teach  an  obedient  people 
"to  lay  down  the  private  for  the  public  sake."  It  is  not  sur- 
prising, therefore,  when  the  Star  Chamber  fines  an  engrosser 
of  corn,  to  find  him  improving  the  occasion  with  the  remark 
that  the  defendant  has  been  "guilty  of  a  most  foule  offense, 
which  the  Prophet  hath  [called]  in  a  very  energeticall  phrase 
grynding  the  faces  of  the  poore,"  and  that  the  dearth  has 
been  caused,  not  by  God,  but  by  "cruell  menn;7J  or  taking 
part  in  the  proceedings  of  the  Privy  Council  at  a  time  when 
it  is  pressing  justices,  apparently  not  without  success,  to  com- 
pel the  East  Anglian  clothiers  to  raise  the  wages  of  spinners 
and  weavers;  or  serving  on  the  Lincolnshire  sub-committee 
of  the  Commission  on  the  Relief  of  the  Poor,  which  was  ap- 
pointed in  January  163 1.74 

"A  bishop,"  observed  Laud,  in  answer  to  the  attack  of 
Lord  Saye  and  Sele,  "may  preach  the  Gospel  more  publicly 
and  to  far  greater  edification  in  a  court  of  judicature,  or  at 
a  Council-table,  where  great  men  are  met  together  to  draw 


THE   GROWTH   OF   INDIVIDUALISM 

things  to  an  issue,  than  many  preachers  in  their  several 
carges  can."  75  The  Church,  which  had  abandoned  the  pre- 
tension itself  to  control  society,  found  some  compensation  in 
the  reflection  that  its  doctrines  were  not  wholly  without  in- 
fluence in  impressing  the  principles  which  were  applied  by 
the  State.  The  history  of  the  rise  of  individual  liberty — to 
use  a  question-begging  phrase — in  economic  affairs  follows 
somewhat  the  same  course  as  does  its  growth  in  the  more 
important  sphere  of  religion,  and  is  not  unconnected  with  it. 
The  conception  of  religion  as  a  thing  private  and  individual 
does  not  emerge  until  after  a  century  in  which  *eligious  free- 
dom normally  means  the  freedom  of  the  State  to  prescribe 
religion,  not  the  freedom  of  the  individual  to  worship  God 
as  he  pleases.  The  assertion  of  economic  liberty  as  a  natural 
right  comes  at  the  close  of  a  period  in  which,  while  a  reli- 
gious phraseology  was  retained  and  a  religious  interpretation 
of  social  institutions  was  often  sincerely  held,  the  supernat- 
ural sanction  had  been  increasingly  merged  in  doctrines 
based  on  reasons  of  state  and  public  expediency.  "Jerusalem 
.  .  .  stands  not  for  the  City  and  the  State  only  .  .  .  nor  for 
the  Temple  and  the  Church  only,  but  jointly  for  both."  76  In 
identifying  the  maintenance  of  public  morality  with  the  spas- 
modic activities  of  an  incompetent  Government,  the  Church 
had  built  its  house  upon  the  sand.  It  did  not  require  pro- 
phetic gifts  to  foresee  that  the  fall  of  the  City  would  be 
followed  by  the  destruction  of  the  Temple. 

Ill     THE  GROWTH  OF  INDIVIDUALISM 

Though  the  assertion  of  the  traditional  economic  ethics 
continued  to  be  made  by  one  school  of  churchmen  down  to 
the  meeting  of  the  Long  Parliament,  it  was  increasingly  the 
voice  of  the  past  appealing  to  an  alien  generation.  The  ex- 
pression of  a  theory  of  society  which  had  made  religion  su- 
preme over  all  secular  affairs,  it  had  outlived  the  synthesis 
in  which  it  had  been  an  element,  and  survived,  an  archaic 
fragment,  into  an  age  to  whose  increasing  individualism  the 
idea  of  corporate  morality  was  as  objectionable  as  that  of  ec- 
clesiastical discipline  by  bishops  and  archdeacons  was  be- 
coming to  its  religion.  The  collision  between  the  prevalent 
practice,  and  what  still  purported  to  be  the  teaching  of  the 
Church,  is  almost  the  commonest  theme  of  the  economic  lit- 
erature of  the  period  from  1550  to  1640;  of  much  of  it,  in- 


ISO  THE    CHURCH   OF  ENGLAND 

deed,  it  is  the  occasion.  Whatever  the  Church  might  say,  men 
had  asked  interest  for  loans,  and  charged  what  prices  the 
market  would  stand,  at  the  very  zenith  of  the  Age  of  Faith. 
But  then,  except  in  the  great  commercial  centers  and  in  the 
high  finance  of  the  Papacy  and  of  secular  Governments, 
their  transactions  had  been  petty  and  individual,  d&  occa- 
sional shift  to  meet  an  emergency  or  seize  an  opportunity. 
The  new  thing  in  the  England  of  the  sixteenth  century  was 
that  devices  that  had  formerly  been  occasional  were  now 
woven  into  the  very  texture  of  the  industrial  and  commercial 
civilization  which  was  developing  in  the  later  years  of  Eliza- 
beth, and  whose  subsequent  enormous  expansion  was  to  s;ive 
English  society  its  characteristic  quality  and  tone.  Fifty 
years  later,  Harrington,  in  a  famous  passage,  described  how 
the  ruin  of  the  feudal  nobility  by  the  Tudors,  by  democra- 
tizing the  ownership  of  land,  had  prepared  the  way  for  the 
bourgeois  republic.77  His  hint  of  the  economic  changes  which 
preceded  the  Civil  War  might  be  given  a  wider  application. 
The  age  of  Elizabeth  saw  a  steady  growth  of  capitalism  in 
textiles  and  mining,  a  great  increase  of  foreign  trade  and  an 
outburst  of  joint-stock  enterprise  in  connection  with  it,  the 
beginnings  of  something  like  deposit  banking  in  the  hands 
of  the  scriveners,  and  the  growth,  aided  by  the  fall  of  Ant- 
werp and  the  Government's  own  financial  necessities,  of  a 
money-market  with  an  almost  modern  technique — specula- 
tion, futures  and  arbitrage  transactions — in  London.  The  fu- 
ture lay  with  the  classes  who  sprang  to  wealth  and  influence 
with  the  expansion  of  commerce  in  the  later  years  of  the 
century,  and  whose  religious  and  political  aspirations  were, 
two  generations  later,  to  overthrow  the  monarchy. 

An  organized  money-market  has  many  advantages.  But  it 
is  not  a  school  of  social  ethics  or  of  political  responsibility. 
Finance,  being  essentially  impersonal,  a  matter  of  opportuni- 
ties, security  and  risks,  acted  among  other  causes  as  a  solvent 
of  the  sentiment,  fostered  both  by  the  teaching  of  the  Church 
and  the  decencies  of  social  intercourse  among  neighbors, 
which  regarded  keen  bargaining  as  "sharp  practice. "  In  the 
half-century  which  followed  the  Reformation,  thanks  to  the 
collapse  of  sterling  on  the  international  market,  as  a  result  of 
a  depreciated  currency,  war,  and  a  foreign  debt  contracted 
on  ruinous  terms,  the  state  of  the  foreign  exchanges  was  the 
obsession  of  publicists  and  politicians.  Problems  of  currency 
and  credit  lend  themselves  more  readilv  than  most  economic 


THE   GROWTH   OF  INDIVIDUALISM  iSt 

questions  to  discussion  in  terms  of  mechanical  causation.  It 
was  in  the  long  debate  provoked  by  the  rise  in  prices  and  th«* 
condition  of  the  exchanges,  that  the  psychological  assump* 
tions,  which  were  afterwards  to  be  treated  by  economists  as 
of  self-evident  and  universal  validity,  were  first  ham- 
mered out. 

"We  see/7  wrote  Malynes,  "how  one  thing  driveth  or  en* 
forceth  another,  like  as  in  a  clock  where  there  are  many 
wheels,  the  first  wheel  being  stirred  driveth  the  next  and  that 
the  third  and  so  forth,  till  the  last  that  moveth  the  instru- 
ment that  striketh  the  clock;  or  like  as  in  a  press  going  in 
a  strait,  where  the  foremost  is  driven  by  him  that  is  next  to 
him,  and  the  next  by  him  that  followeth  him."  <s  The  spirit 
of  modern  business  could  hardly  be  more  aptly  described. 
Conservative  writers  denounced  it  as  fostering  a  soulless  in- 
dividualism, but,  needless  to  say,  their  denunciations  were  as 
futile  as  they  were  justified.  It  might  be  possible  to  put  fear 
into  the  heart  of  the  village  dealer  who  bought  cheap  and 
sold  dear,  or  of  the  pawnbroker  who  took  a  hundred  quarters 
of  wheat  when  he  had  lent  ninety,  with  the  warning  that 
''the  devices  of  men  cannot  be  concealed  from  Almighty 
God."  To  a  great  clothier,  or  to  a  capitalist  like  Pallavicino, 
Spinola,  or  Thomas  Gresham,  who  managed  the  Government 
business  in  Antwerp,  such  sentiments  were  foolishness,  and 
usurious  interest  appeared,  not  bad  morals,  but  bad  business. 
Moving,  as  they  did,  in  a  world  where  loans  were  made,  not 
to  meet  the  temporary  difficulty  of  an  unfortunate  neigh- 
bor, but  as  a  profitable  investment  on  the  part  ot  not  too 
scrupulous  business  men,  who  looked  after  themselves  and 
expected  others  to  do  the  same,  they  had  scanty  sympathy 
with  doctrines  which  reflected  the  spirit  of  mutual  aid  not 
unnatural  in  the  small  circle  of  neighbors  who  formed  the 
ordinary  village  or  borough  in  rural  England. 

It  was  a  natural  result  of  their  experience  that,  without 
the  formal  enunciation  of  any  theory  of  economic  individ- 
ualism, they  should  throw  their  weight  against  the  tradi- 
tional restrictions,  resent  the  attempts  made  by  preachers 
and  popular  movements  to  apply  doctrines  of  charity  and 
"good  conscience"  to  the  impersonal  mechanism  of  large- 
scale  transactions,  and  seek  to  bring  public  policy  more  into 
accordance  with  their  economic  practice.  The  opposition  to 
the  Statutes  against  depopulation  offered  by  the  self-interest 
of  the  gentry  was  being  supported  in  the  latter  years  of  Eliz- 


152  THE   CHURCH   OP   ENGLAND 

abeth  by  free-trade  arguments  in  the  House  of  Commons, 
and  the  last  Act,  which  was  passed  in  1597,  expressly  al- 
lowed land  to  be  laid  down  to  pasture  for  the  purpose  of 
giving  it  a  rest.79  From  at  any  rate  the  middle  of  the  cen- 
tury, the  fixing  of  prices  by  municipal  authorities  and  by  the 
Government  was  regarded  with  skepticism  by  the  more  ad- 
vanced economic  theorists,  and  towards  the  end  of  the  cen- 
tury it  produced  complaints  that,  since  it  weakened  the 
farmer's  incentive  to  grow  corn,  its  results  were  the  precise 
opposite  of  those  intended.80  As  markets  widened,  the  con- 
trol of  the  middleman  who  dealt  in  wool  and  grain,  though 
strictly  enforced  in  theory,  showed  unmistakable  signs  of 
breaking  down  in  practice.  Gresham  attacked  the  prohibition 
of  usury,  and  normally  stipulated  that  financiers  who  sub- 
scribed on  his  inducement  to  public  loans  should  be  indem- 
nified against  legal  proceedings  81  Nor  could  he  well  have 
done  otherwise,  for  the  sentiment  of  the  City  was  that  of 
the  merchant  in  Wilson's  Dialogue:  "What  man  is  so  mad- 
de  to  deliver  his  moneye  out  of  his  own  possession  for 
naughte?  or  whoe  is  he  that  will  not  make  of  his  owne  the 
best  he  can?"  SJ  With  such  a  wind  of  doctrine  in  their  sails 
men  were  not  far  from  the  days  of  complete  freedom  of 
contract. 

Most  significant  of  all,  economic  interests  were  already  ap- 
pealing to  the  political  theory  which,  when  finally  systema- 
tized by  Locke,  was  to  prove  that  the  State  which  interferes 
with  property  and  business  destroys  its  own  title  to  exist 
"All  free  subject,"  declared  a  Committee  of  the  House  of 
Commons  in  1604,  "are  born  inheritable,  as  to  their  land, 
so  also  to  the  free  exercise  of  their  industry,  in  those  trades 
whereto  they  apply  themselves  and  whereby  they  are  to 
live.  Merchandise  being  the  chief  and  richest  of  all  other,  and 
of  greater  extent  and  importance  than  all  the  rest,  it  is 
against  the  natural  right  and  liberty  of  the  subjects  of  Eng- 
land to  restrain  it  into  the  hands  of  some  few  "  s '  The  process 
by  which  natural  justice,  imperfectly  embodied  in  positive 
law,  was  replaced  as  the  source  of  authority  by  positive  law 
which  might  or  might  not  be  the  expression  of  natural  jus- 
tice, had  its  analogy  in  the  rejection  by  social  theory  of  the 
whole  conception  of  an  objective  standard  of  economic 
equity.  The  law  of  nature  had  been  invoked  by  medieval 
writers  as  a  moral  restraint  upon  economic  self-interest.  By 
the  seventeenth  century,  a  significant  revolution  had  taken 


THE  GROWTH   OF   INDIVIDUALISM  153 

place.  "Nature"  had  come  to  connote,  not  divine  ordinance, 
but  human  appetites,  and  natural  rights  were  invoked  by  the 
individualism  of  the  age  as  a  reason  why  self-interest  should 
be  given  free  play. 

The  effect  of  these  practical  exigencies  and  intellectual 
changes  was  seen  in  a  reversal  of  policy  on  the  part  of  the 
State.  In  1571  the  Act  of  1552,  which  had  prohibited  all 
interest  as  a  "vyce  moste  odyous  and  detestable,  as  in  dy- 
vers  places  of  the  hollie  Scripture  it  is  evydent  to  be  seen," 
had  been  repealed,  after  a  debate  in  the  House  which  re- 
vealed the  revolt  of  the  plain  man  against  the  theorists  who 
had  triumphed  twenty  years  before,  and  his  determination 
that  the  law  should  not  impose  on  business  a  Utopian  moral- 
ity.84 The  exaction  of  interest  ceased  to  be  a  criminal  offense, 
provided  that  the  rate  did  not  exceed  ten  per  cent.,  though  it 
still  remained  open  to  a  debtor,  in  the  improbable  event  of 
his  thinking  it  expedient  to  jeopardize  his  chance  of  future 
advances,  to  take  civil  proceedings  to  recover  any  payment 
made  in  excess  of  the  principal.  This  qualified  condonation 
of  usury  on  the  part  of  the  State  naturally  reacted  upon  re- 
ligious opinion  The  Crown  was  supreme  ruler  of  the  Church 
of  Christ,  and  it  was  not  easy  for  a  loyal  Church  to  be  more 
fastidious  than  its  head.  Moderate  interest,  if  without  legal 
protection,  was  at  any  rate  not  unlawful,  and  it  is  difficult  to 
damn  with  conviction  vices  of  which  the  degrees  have  been 
adjusted  on  a  sliding  scale  by  an  Act  of  Parliament.  Objec- 
tive economic  science  was  beginning  its  disillusioning  career, 
in  the  form  of  discussions  on  the  rise  in  prices,  the  mech- 
anism of  the  money-market,  and  the  balance  of  trade,  by 
publicists  concerned,  not  to  point  a  moral,  but  to  analyze 
forces  so  productive  of  profit  to  those  interested  in  their 
operation.  Since  Calvin's  indulgence  to  interest,  critics  of 
the  traditional  doctrine  could  argue  that  religion  itself 
spoke  with  an  uncertain  voice. 

Such  developments  inevitably  affected  the  tone  in  which 
the  discussion  of  economic  ethics  was  carried  on  by  the  di- 
vines, and  even  before  the  end  of  the  sixteenth  century, 
though  they  did  not  dream  of  abandoning  the  denunciation 
of  unconscionable  bargains,  they  were  surrounding  it  with 
qualifications.  The  Decades  of  Bullinger,  of  which  three 
English  translations  were  made  in  the  ten  years  following 
his  death,  and  which  Convocation  in  1586  required  to  be  ob* 
tained  and  studied  by  all  the  inferior  clergy,  indicated  a 


154  THE    CHURCH    OF   ENGLAND 

via  media.  As  uncompromising  as  any  medieval  writer  in  his 
hatred  of  the  sin  of  covetousness,  he  denounces  with  all  the 
bid  fervor  oppressive  contracts  which  grind  the  poor.  But 
he  is  less  intolerant  of  economic  motives  than  most  of  his 
predecessors,  and  concedes,  with  Calvin,  that,  before  inter- 
est is  condemned  as  usury,  it  is  necessary  to  consider  both 
the  terms  of  the  loan  and  the  position  of  borrower  and 
lender. 

The  stricter  school  of  religious  opinion  continued  to  cling 
to  the  traditional  theory  down  to  the  Civil  War.  Conserva- 
tive divines  took  advantage  of  the  section  in  the  Act  of  1571 
declaring  that  "all  usurie  being  forbydden  by  the  lawe  of 
God  is  synne  and  detestable,"  to  argue  that  the  Statute  had 
in  reality  altered  nothing,  and  that  the  State  left  it  to  the 
Church  to  prevent  bargains  which,  for  reasons  of  practical 
expediency,  it  did  not  think  fit  to  prohibit,  but  which  it  did 
not  encourage  and  declined  to  enforce  It  is  in  obedience  to 
such  doctrines  that  a  scrupulous  parson  refuses  a  cure  until 
he  is  assured  that  the  money  which  will  be  paid  to  him  comes 
from  the  rent  of  land,  not  from  interest  on  capital. 8r>  But, 
even  so,  there  are  difficulties  The  parson  of  Kingham  be- 
queaths a  cow  to  the  poor  of  Burford,  which  is  uset  to  hire 
for  a  year  or  two  for  four  shillings  a  year,"  the  money 
used  for  their  assistance.  Cows  are  mortal,  and  this  com- 
munal cow  is  uvery  like  to  have  perished  through  casualty 
and  ill-keeping  "  8('  Will  not  the  poor  be  surer  of  their  money 
if  the  cow  is  disposed  of  for  cash  down?  So  it  is  sold  to  the 
man  who  previously  hired  it,  and  the  interest  spent  on  the 
poor  instead.  Is  this  usury?  Is  it  usury  to  invest  money  in 
business  in  order  to  provide  an  income  for  those,  like  wid- 
ows and  orphans,  who  cannot  trade  with  it  themselves?  If 
it  is  lawful  to  buy  a  rent-charge  or  to  share  in  trading  prof- 
its, what  is  the  particular  criminality  of  charging  a  price 
for  a  loan?  Why  should  a  creditor,  who  may  himself  be  poor, 
make  a  loan  gratis,  in  order  to  put  money  into  the  pocket  of 
a  wealthy  capitalist,  who  uses  the  advance  to  corner  the 
wool  crop  or  to  speculate  on  the  exchanges? 

To  such  questions  liberal  theologians  answered  that  the 
crucial  point  was  not  the  letter  of  the  law  which  forbad  the 
breeding  of  barren  metal,  but  the  observance  of  Christian 
charity  in  economic,  as  in  other,  transactions.  Their  oppo- 
nents appealed  to  the  text  of  Scripture  and  the  law  of  the 
Church,  argued  that  usury  differed,  not  merely  in  degree,  but 


THE   GROWTH   OF   INDIVIDUALISM  155 

in  kind,  from  payments  which,  like  rent  and  profits,  were 
morally  unobjectionable  provided  that  they  were  not  extor- 
tionate in  amount,  and  insisted  that  usury  was  to  be  inter- 
preted as  "whatever  is  taken  for  a  loan  above  the  principal.'* 
The  literature  of  the  subject  was  voluminous.  But  it  was  ob- 
solete almost  before  it  was  produced.  For,  whether  theolo- 
gians and  moralists  condemned  all  interest,  or  only  some  in- 
terest, as  contrary  to  Christian  ethics,  the  assumption  im- 
plied in  their  very  disagreement  had  been  that  economic 
relations  belonged  to  a  province  of  which,  in  the  last  resort, 
the  Church  was  master.  That  economic  transactions  were 
one  department  of  ethical  conduct,  and  to  be  judged,  like 
other  parts  of  it,  by  spiritual  criteria;  that,  whatever  con- 
cessions the  State  might  see  fit  to  make  to  human  frailty,  a 
certain  standard  of  economic  morality  was  involved  in  mem- 
bership of  the  Christian  Church;  that  it  was  the  function 
of  ecclesiastical  authorities,  whoever  they  might  be,  to  take 
the  action  needed  to  bring  home  to  men  their  social  obliga- 
tions— such  doctrines  were  still  common  ground  to  all  sec- 
tions of  religious  thought.  It  was  precisely  this  whole  con- 
ception of  a  social  theory  based  ultimately  on  religion  which 
was  being  discredited.  While  rival  authorities  were  discuss- 
ing the  correct  interpretation  of  economic  ethics,  the  flank 
of  both  was  turned  by  the  growth  of  a  powerful  body  of 
lay  opinion,  which  argued  that  economics  were  one  thing 
and  ethics  another. 

Usury,  a  summary  name  for  all  kinds  of  extortion,  was  the 
issue  in  which  the  whole  controversy  over  "good  conscience" 
in  bargaining  came  to  a  head,  and  such  questions  were  only 
one  illustration  of  the  immense  problems  with  which  the 
rise  of  a  commercial  civilization  confronted  a  Church  whose 
social  ethics  still  professed  to  be  those  of  the  Bible,  the 
Fathers  and  the  Schoolmen.  A  score  of  books,  garnished  with 
citations  from  Scripture  and  from  the  canonists,  were  written 
to  answer  them.  Many  of  them  are  learned ;  some  are  almost 
readable.  But  it  may  be  doubted  whether,  even  in  their  own 
day,  they  satisfied  any  one  but  their  authors.  The  truth  is 
that,  in  spite  of  the  sincerity  with  which  it  was  held  that 
the  transactions  of  business  must  somehow  be  amendable  to 
the  moral  law,  the  code  of  practical  ethics,  in  which  that 
claim  as  expressed,  had  been  forged  to  meet  the  conditions 
of  a  very  different  environment  from  that  of  commercial 
England  in  the  seventeenth  century. 


156  THE   CHURCH   OF   ENGLAND 

The  most  crucial  and  the  most  difficult  of  all  political 
questions  is  that  which  turns  on  the  difference  between  public 
and  private  morality.  The  problem  which  it  presents  in  the 
relations  between  States  is  a  commonplace.  But,  since  its 
essence  is  the  difficulty  of  applying  the  same  moral  standard 
to  decisions  which  affect  large  masses  of  men  as  to  those  in 
which  only  individuals  are  involved,  it  emerges  in  a  hardly 
less  acute  form  in  the  sphere  of  economic  life,  as  soon  as  its 
connections  ramify  widely,  and  the  unit  is  no  longer  the 
solitary  producer,  but  a  group  To  argue,  in  the  manner  of 
Machiavelli,  that  there  is  one  rule  for  business  and  another 
for  private  life,  is  to  open  a  door  to  an  orgy  of  unscrupulous- 
ness  before  which  the  mind  recoils.  To  argue  that  there  is  no 
difference  at  all  is  to  lay  down  a  principle  which  few  men 
who  have  faced  the  difficulty  in  practice  will  be  prepared  to 
endorse  as  of  invariable  application,  and  incidentally  to  ex- 
pose the  idea  of  morality  itself  to  discredit  by  subjecting  it 
to  an  almost  intolerable  strain.  The  practical  result  of  sen- 
timentality is  too  often  a  violent  reaction  toward  the  baser 
kinds  of  Realpoliiik. 

With  the  expansion  of  finance  and  international  trade  in 
the  sixteenth  century,  it  was  this  problem  which  faced  the 
Church.  Granted  that  I  should  love  my  neighbor  as  myself, 
the  questions  which,  under  modern  conditions  of  large-scale 
organization,  remain  for  solution  are,  Who  precisely  is  my 
neighbor?  and,  How  exactly  am  I  to  make  my  love  for  him 
effective  in  practice?  To  these  questions  the  conventional  re- 
ligious teaching  supplied  no  answer,  for  it  had  not  even  real- 
ized that  they  could  be  put.  It  had  tried  to  moralize  economic 
relations  by  treating  every  transaction  as  a  case  of  personal 
conduct,  involving  personal  responsibility.  In  an  age  of  im- 
personal finance,  world-markets  and  a  capitalist  organiza- 
tion of  industry,  its  traditional  social  doctrines  had  no  spe- 
cific to  offer,  and  were  merely  repeated,  when,  in  order  to  be 
effective,  they  should  have  been  thought  out  again  from  the 
beginning  and  formulated  in  new  and  living  terms.  It  had 
endeavored  to  protect  the  peasant  and  the  craftsman  against 
the  oppression  of  the  money-lender  and  the  monopolist. 
Faced  with  the  problems  of  a  wage-earning  proletariat,  it 
could  do  no  more  than  repeat,  with  meaningless  iteration,  its 
traditional  lore  as  to  the  duties  of  master  to  servant  and 
servant  to  master.  It  had  insisted  that  all  men  were  breth- 
ren. But  it  did  not  occur  to  it  to  point  out  that,  as  a  result 


THE   GROWTH   OF   INDIVIDUALISM  157 

of  the  new  economic  imperialism  which  was  beginning  to 
develop  in  the  seventeenth  century,  the  brethren  of  the  Eng- 
lish merchant  were  the  Africans  whom  he  kidnaped  for  slav- 
ery in  America,  or  the  American  Indians  whom  he  stripped 
of  their  lands,  or  the  Indian  craftsmen  from  whom  he  bought 
muslins  and  silks  at  starvation  prices.  Religion  had  not  yet 
learned  to  console  itself  for  the  practical  difficulty  of  applying 
its  moral  principles  by  clasping  the  comfortable  formula  that 
for  the  transaction  of  economic  life  no  moral  principles  exist. 
But,  for  the  problems  involved  in  the  association  of  men  for 
economic  purposes  on  the  grand  scale  which  was  to  be  in- 
creasingly the  rule  in  the  future,  the  social  doctrines  ad- 
vanced from  the  pulpit  offered,  in  their  traditional  form, 
little  guidance.  Their  practical  ineffectiveness  prepared  the 
way  for  their  theoretical  abandonment. 

They  were  abandoned  because,  on  the  whole,  they  deserved 
to  be  abandoned.  The  social  teaching  of  the  Church  had 
ceased  to  count,  because  the  Church  itself  had  ceased  to 
think.  Energy  in  economic  action,  realist  intelligence  in  eco- 
nomic thought — these  qualities  were  to  be  the  note  of  the 
seventeenth  century,  when  once  the  confusion  of  the  Civil 
War  had  died  down  When  mankind  is  faced  with  the  choice 
between  exhilarating  activities  and  piety  imprisoned  in  a 
shriveled  mass  of  desiccated  formulae,  it  will  choose  the  for- 
mer, though  the  energy  be  brutal  and  the  intelligence  narrow. 
In  the  age  of  Bacon  and  Descartes,  bursting  with  clamorous 
interests  and  eager  ideas,  fruitful,  above  all,  in  the  germs  of 
economic  speculation,  from  which  was  to  grow  the  new  sci- 
ence of  Political  Arithmetic,  the  social  theory  of  the  Church 
of  England  turned  its  face  from  the  practical  world,  to  pore 
over  doctrines  which,  had  their  original  authors  been  as  im- 
pervious to  realities  as  their  later  exponents,  would  never 
have  been  formulated.  Naturally  it  was  shouldered  aside.  It 
was  neglected  because  it  had  become  negligible. 

The  defect  was  fundamental.  It  made  itself  felt  in  coun- 
tries where  there  was  no  Reformation,  no  Puritan  movement, 
no  common  law  jealous  of  its  rights  and  eager  to  prune  ec- 
cleastical  pretensions.  But  in  England  there  were  all  three, 
and,  from  the  beginning  of  the  last  quarter  of  the  sixteenth 
century,  ecclesiastical  authorities  who  attempted  to  enforce 
traditional  morality  had  to  reckon  with  a  temper  which  de- 
nied their  right  to  exercise  any  jurisdiction  at  all,  above  all, 
any  jurisdiction  interfering  with  economic  matters.  It  was 


158  THE   CHURCH   OF   ENGLAND 

not  merely  that  there  was  the  familiar  objection  of  the  plain 
man  that  parsons  know  nothing  of  business — that  "it  is  not 
in  simple  divines  to  show  what  contract  is  lawful  and  what 
is  not."  87  More  important,  there  was  the  opposition  of  the 
common  lawyers  to  part,  at  least,  of  the  machinery  of  ecclesi- 
astical discipline.  Bancroft  in  1605  complained  to  the  Privy 
Council  that  the  judges  were  endeavoring  to  confine  the 
jurisdiction  of  the  ecclesiastical  courts  to  testamentary  and 
matrimonial  cases,  and  alleged  that,  of  more  than  five  hun- 
dred prohibitions  issued  to  stop  proceedings  in  the  Court  of 
Arches  since  the  accession  of  Elizabeth,  not  more  than  one 
in  twenty  could  be  sustained.88  "As  things  are,"  wrote  two 
years  later  the  author  of  a  treatise  on  the  civil  and  ecclesias- 
tical law,  "neither  jurisdiction  knowes  their  owne  bounds, 
but  one  snatcheth  from  the  other,  in  maner  as  in  a  batable 
ground  lying  betweene  two  kingdomes  "  89  The  jurisdiction 
of  the  Court  of  High  Commission  suffered  in  the  same  way. 
In  the  last  resort  appeals  from  the  ecclesiastical  courts  went 
either  to  it  or  to  the  Court  of  Delegates.  From  the  latter  part 
of  the  sixteenth  century  down  to  the  removal  of  Coke  from 
the  Bench  in  1616,  the  judges  were  from  time  to  time  stay- 
ing proceedings  before  the  Court  of  High  Commission  by 
prohibitions,  or  discharging  offenders  imprisoned  by  it.  In 
1577,  for  example,  they  released  on  a  writ  of  Habeas  Corpus 
a  prisoner  committed  by  the  High  Commission  on  a  charge 
of  usury.90 

Most  fundamental  of  all,  there  was  the  growth  of  a  theory 
of  the  Church,  which  denied  the  very  principle  of  a  disci- 
pline exercised  by  bishops  and  archdeacons.  The  acquies- 
cence of  the  laity  in  the  moral  jurisdiction  of  the  clergy  had 
been  accorded  with  less  and  less  readiness  for  two  centuries 
before  the  Reformation.  With  the  growth  under  Elizabeth  of 
a  vigorous  Puritan  movement,  which  had  its  stronghold 
among  the  trading  and  commercial  classes,  that  jurisdiction 
became  to  a  considerable  proportion  of  the  population  little 
less  than  abhorrent.  Their  dislike  of  it  was  based,  of  course, 
on  weightier  grounds  than  its  occasional  interference  in  mat- 
ters of  business.  But  their  attitude  had  as  an  inevitable  re- 
sult that,  with  the  disparagement  of  the  whole  principle  of 
the  traditional  ecclesiastical  discipline,  that  particular  use  of 
it  was  also  discredited.  It  was  not  that  Puritanism  implied 
a  greater  laxity  in  social  relations.  On  the  contrary,  in  its 
earlier  phases  it  stood,  at  least  in  theory,  for  a  stricter  disci- 


THE    GROWTH    OF    INDIVIDUALISM  159 

pline  of  the  life  of  the  individual,  alike  in  his  business  and  in 
his  pleasures.  But  it  repudiated  as  anti-Christian  the  organs 
through  which  such  discipline  had  in  fact  been  exercised. 
When  the  Usury  Bill  of  1571  was  being  discussed  in  the 
House  of  Commons,  reference  to  the  canon  law  was  met 
by  the  protest  that  the  rules  of  the  canon  law  on  the  matter 
were  abolished,  and  that  "they  should  be  no  more  remem- 
bered than  they  are  followed."  91  Feeling  against  the  system 
rose  steadily  during  the  next  two  generations;  excommuni- 
cations, when  courts  ventured  to  resort  to  them,  were  freely 
disregarded;92  and  by  the  thirties  of  the  seventeenth  century, 
under  the  influence  of  Laud's  regime,  the  murmur  was 
threatening  to  become  a  hurricane.  Then  came  the  Long 
Parliament,  the  fierce  denunciations  in  both  Houses  of  the 
interference  of  the  clergy  in  civil  affairs,  and  the  legislation 
abolishing  the  Court  of  High  Commission,  depriving  the  or- 
dinary ecclesiastical  courts  of  penal  jurisdiction,  and  finally, 
with  the  abolition  of  episcopacy,  sweeping  them  away  al- 
together. 

"Not  many  good  days,"  wrote  Penn,  "since  ministers  med- 
dled so  much  in  laymen's  business."  'J>i  That  sentiment  was  a 
dogma  on  which,  after  the  Restoration,  both  Cavalier  and 
Roundhead  could  agree.  It  inevitably  reacted,  not  only  upon 
the  practical  powers  of  the  clergy,  which  in  any  case  had 
long  been  feeble,  but  on  the  whole  conception  of  reKgion 
which  regarded  it  as  involving  the  control  of  economic  self- 
interest  by  what  Laud  had  called  "the  body  of  the  Church." 
The  works  of  Sanderson  and  of  Jeremy  Taylor,  continuing 
an  earlier  tradition,  reasserted  with  force  and  eloquence  the 
view  that  the  Christian  is  bound  by  his  faith  to  a  rule  of  life 
which  finds  expression  in  equity  in  bargaining  and  in  works 
of  mercy  to  his  neighbors.04  But  the  conception  that  the 
Church  possessed,  of  its  own  authority,  an  independent 
standard  of  social  values,  which  it  could  apply  as  a  crite- 
rion to  the  practical  affairs  of  the  economic  world,  grew 
steadily  weaker.  The  result,  neither  immediate  nor  intended, 
but  inevitable,  was  the  tacit  denial  of  spiritual  significance 
in  the  transactions  of  business  and  in  the  relations  of  or- 
ganized society.  Repudiating  the  right  of  religion  to  advance 
any  social  theory  distinctively  its  own,  that  attitude  became 
itself  the  most  tyrannical  and  paralyzing  of  theories.  It  may 
be  called  Indifferentism. 

The  change  had  begun  before  the  Civil  War.  It  was  com- 


THE   CHURCH   OF   ENGLAND 

pleted  with  the  Restoration,  and,  still  more,  with  the  Revo- 
lution. In  the  eighteenth  century  it  is  almost  superfluous  to 
examine  the  teaching  of  the  Church  of  England  as  to  social 
ethics.  For  it  brings  no  distinctive  contribution,  and,  except 
by  a  few  eccentrics,  the  very  conception  of  the  Church  as 
an  independent  moral  authority,  whose  standards  may  be  in 
sharp  antithesis  to  social  conventions,  has  been  abandoned. 

An  institution  which  possesses  no  philosophy  of  its  own 
inevitably  accepts  that  which  happens  to  be  fashionable. 
What  set  the  tone  of  social  thought  in  the  eighteenth  century 
was  partly  the  new  Political  Arithmetic,  which  had  come  to 
maturity  at  the  Restoration,  and  which,  as  was  to  be  expect- 
ed in  the  first  great  age  of  English  natural  science — the  age 
of  Newton,  of  Halley,  and  of  the  Royal  Society— drew  its 
inspiration,  not  from  religion  or  morals,  but  from  mathe- 
matics and  physics.  It  was  still  more  the  political  theory  as- 
sociated with  the  name  of  Locke,  but  popularized  and  de- 
based by  a  hundred  imitators.  Society  is  not  a  community  of 
classes  with  varying  functions,  united  to  each  other  by  mu- 
tual obligations  arising  from  their  relation  to  a  common  end. 
It  is  a  joint-stock  company  rather  than  an  organism,  and 
the  liabilities  of  the  shareholder  are  strictly  limited.  They 
enter  it  in  order  to  insure  the  rights  already  vested  in  them 
by  the  immutable  laws  of  nature.  The  State,  a  matter  of 
convenience,  not  of  supernatural  sanctions,  exists  for  the 
protection  of  those  rights,  and  fulfills  its  object  in  so  far  as, 
by  maintaining  contractual  freedom,  it  secures  full  scope 
for  their  unfettered  exercise. 

The  most  important  of  such  rights  are  property  rights, 
and  property  rights  attach  mainly,  though  not,  of  course, 
exclusively,  to  the  higher  orders  of  men,  who  hold  the  tan- 
gible, material  "stock1*  of  society.  Those  who  do  not  sub- 
scribe to  the  company  have  no  legal  claim  to  a  share  in 
the  profits,  though  they  have  a  moral  claim  on  the  charity 
of  their  superiors.  Hence  the  curious  phraseology  which 
treats  almost  all  below  the  nobility,  gentry  and  freeholders 
as  "the  poor" — and  the  poor,  it  is  well  known,  are  of  two 
kinds,  "the  industrious  poor,"  who  work  for  their  betters, 
and  "the  idle  poor,"  who  work  for  themselves  Hence  the 
unending  discussions  as  to  whether  "the  laboring  poor"  are 
to  be  classed  among  the  "productive"  or  "unproductive' 
classes — whether  they  are,  or  are  not,  really  worth  their 
keep.  Hence  the  indignant  repudiation  of  the  suggestion  that 


THE   GROWTH   OF   INDIVIDUALISM  161 

any  substantial  amelioration  of  their  lot  could  be  effected 
by  any  kind  of  public  policy.  "It  would  be  easier,  where 
property  was  well  secured,  to  live  without  money  than  with- 
out poor,  .  .  .  who,  as  they  ought  to  be  kept  from  starving, 
so  they  should  receive  nothing  worth  saving'';  the  poor 
"have  nothing  to  stir  them  up  to  be  serviceable  but  their 
wants,  which  it  is  prudence  to  relieve,  but  folly  to  cure"; 
"to  make  society  happy,  it  is  necessary  that  great  numbers 
should  be  wretched  as  well  as  poor."95  Such  sentences  from  a 
work  printed  in  1714  are  not  typical.  But  they  are  straws 
which  show  how  the  wind  is  blowing. 

In  such  an  atmosphere  temperatures  were  naturally  low 
and  equable,  and  enthusiasm,  if  not  a  lapse  in  morals,  was 
an  intellectual  solecism  and  an  error  in  taste.  Religious 
thought  was  not  immune  from  the  same  influence.  It  was 
not  merely  that  the  Church,  which,  as  much  as  the  State, 
was  the  heir  of  the  Revolution  settlement,  reproduced  the 
temper  of  an  aristocratic  society,  as  it  reproduced  its  class 
organization  and  economic  inequalities,  and  was  disposed  too 
often  to  idealize  as  a  virtue  that  habit  of  mean  subservience 
to  wealth  and  social  position,  which,  after  more  than  half 
a  century  of  political  democracy,  is  still  the  characteristic 
and  odious  vice  of  Englishmen.  Not  less  significant  was  the 
fact  that,  apart  from  certain  groups  and  certain  questions,  it 
accepted  the  prevalent  social  philosophy  and  adapted  its 
teaching  to  it.  The  age  in  which  political  theory  was  cast  in 
the  mould  of  religion  had  yielded  to  one  in  which  religious 
thought  was  no  longer  an  imperious  master,  but  a  docile 
pupil  Conspicuous  exceptions  like  Law,  who  reasserted  with 
matchless  power  the  idea  that  Christianity  implies  a  dis- 
tinctive way  of  life,  or  protests  like  Wesley's  sermon  on 
The  Use  of  Money,  merely  heighten  the  impression  of  a 
general  acquiescence  in  the  conventional  ethics.  The  prev- 
alent religious  thought  might  not  unfairly  be  described  as 
morality  tempered  by  prudence,  and  softened  on  occasion  by 
a  rather  sentimental  compassion  for  inferiors.  It  was  the 
natural  counterpart  of  a  social  philosophy  which  repudiated 
teleology,  and  which  substituted  the  analogy  of  a  self-regu- 
lating mechanism,  moved  by  the  weights  and  pulley  of  eco- 
nomic motives,  for  the  theory  which  had  regarded  society 
as  an  organism  composed  of  different  classes  united  by  their 
common  subordination  to  a  spiritual  purpose. 

Such  an  attitude,  with  its  emphasis  on  the  economic  bar- 


162  THE   CHURCH   OF  ENGLAND 

mony  of  apparently  conflicting  interests,  left  small  scope  for 
moral  casuistry.  The  materials  for  the  reformer  were,  indeed, 
abundant  enough.  The  phenomena  of  early  commercial  cap- 
italism— consider  only  the  orgy  of  financial  immorality 
which  culminated  in  1720 — were  of  a  kind  which  might  have 
been  expected  to  shock  even  the  not  over-sensitive  conscience 
of  the  eighteenth  century.  Two  centuries  before,  the  Fug- 
gers  had  been  denounced  by  preachers  and  theologians;  and, 
compared  with  the  men  who  engineered  the  South  Sea  Bub- 
ble, the  Fuggers  had  been  innocents.  In  reality,  religious 
opinion  was  quite  unmoved  by  the  spectacle.  The  traditional 
scheme  of  social  ethics  had  been  worked  out  in  a  simpler 
age;  in  the  commercial  England  of  banking,  and  shipping, 
And  joint-stock  enterprise,  it  seemed,  and  was  called,  a 
Gothic  superstition.  From  the  Restoration  onward  it  was 
quietly  dropped.  The  usurer  and  engrosser  disappear  from 
episcopal  charges.  In  the  popular  manual  called  The  Whole 
Duty  of  Man,96  first  published  in  1658,  and  widely  read 
during  the  following  century,  extortion  and  oppression  still 
figure  as  sins,  but  the  attempt  to  define  what  they  are  is 
frankly  abandoned.  If  preachers  have  not  yet  overtly  iden- 
tified themselves  with  the  view  of  the  natural  man,  expressed 
by  an  eighteenth-century  writer  in  the  words  "trade  is  one 
thing  and  religion  is  another,"  they  imply  a  not  very  differ- 
ent conclusion  by  their  silence  as  to  the  possibility  of  col- 
lisions between  them.  The  characteristic  doctrine  was  one, 
in  fact,  which  left  little  room  for  religious  teaching  as  to 
economic  morality,  because  it  anticipated  the  theory,  later 
epitomized  by  Adam  Smith  in  his  famous  reference  to  the 
invisible  hand,  which  saw  in  economic  self-interest  the  op- 
eration of  a  providential  plan.  "National  commerce,  good 
morals  and  good  government,"  wrote  Dean  Tucker,  of  whom 
Warburton  unkindly  said  that  religion  was  his  trade,  and 
trade  his  religion,  "are  but  part  of  one  general  scheme,  in 
the  designs  of  Providence." 

Naturally,  on  such  a  view,  it  was  unnecessary  for  the 
Church  to  insist  on  commercial  morality,  since  sound  moral- 
ity coincided  with  commercial  wisdom.  The  existing  order, 
except  in  so  far  as  the  short-sighted  enactments  of  Govern- 
ments interfered  with  it,  was  the  natural  order,  and  the 
order  established  by  nature  was  the  order  established  by 
God.  Most  educated  men,  in  the  middle  of  the  centurv, 


THE   GROWTH   OF  INDIVIDUALISM  163 

would  have  found  their  philosophy  expressed  in  the  lines  of 

P  '        Thus  God  and  Nature  formed  the  general  frame, 
And  bade  self-love  and  social  be  the  same. 

Naturally,  again,  such  an  attitude  precluded  a  critical  ex- 
amination of  institutions,  and  left  as  the  sphere  of  Christian 
charity  only  those  parts  of  life  which  could  be  reserved  for 
philanthropy,  precisely  because  they  fell  outside  that  larger 
area  of  normal  human  relations,  in  which  the  promptings  of 
self-interest  provided  an  all-sufficient  motive  and  rule  of 
conduct.  It  was,  therefore,  in  the  sphere  of  providing  succor 
for  the  non-combatants  and  for  the  wounded,  not  in  inspir- 
ing the  main  army,  that  the  social  work  of  the  Church  was 
conceived  to  lie.  Its  characteristic  expressions  in  the  eight- 
eenth century  were  the  relief  of  the  poor,  the  care  of  the 
sick,  and  the  establishment  of  schools.  In  spite  of  the  genu- 
ine, if  somewhat  unctuous,  solicitude  for  the  spiritual  welfare 
of  the  poorer  classes,  which  inspired  the  Evangelical  revival, 
religion  abandoned  the  fundamental  brain-work  of  criticism 
and  construction  to  the  rationalist  and  the  humanitarian. 
Surprise  has  sometimes  been  expressed  that  the  Church 
should  not  have  been  more  effective  in  giving  inspiration 
and  guidance  during  the  immense  economic  reorganization  to 
which  tradition  has  assigned  the  not  very  felicitous  name  of 
the  "Industrial  Revolution."  It  did  not  give  it,  because  it  did 
not  possess  it.  There  were,  no  doubt,  special  conditions  to 
account  for  its  silence — mere  ignorance  and  inefficiency,  the 
supposed  teachings  of  political  economy,  and,  after  1790, 
the  terror  of  all  humanitarian  movements  inspired  by  France. 
But  the  explanation  of  its  attitude  is  to  be  sought,  less  in 
the  peculiar  circumstances  of  the  moment,  than  in  the  prev- 
alence of  a  temper  which  accepted  the  established  order  of 
class  relations  as  needing  no  vindication  before  any  higher 
tribunal,  and  which  made  religion,  not  its  critic  or  its  ac- 
cuser, but  its  anodyne,  its  apologist,  and  its  drudge.  It  was 
not  that  there  was  any  relapse  into  abnormal  inhumanity. 
It  was  that  the  very  idea  that  the  Church  possessed  an  inde- 
pendent standard  of  values,  to  which  social  institutions  were 
amenable,  had  been  abandoned.  The  surrender  had  been 
made  long  before  the  battle  began.  The  spiritual  blindness 
which  made  possible  the  general  acquiescence  in  the  horrors 
of  the  early  factory  system  was,  not  a  novelty,  but  the  habit 
of  a  centurv. 


CHAPTER  IV 

The  Puritan  Movement 

"And  the  Lorde  was  with  Joseph,  and  he  was  a  luckie  lelowe  " 
Genets  xxxix  2  (Tyndale's  translation) 

BY  the  end  of  the  sixteenth  century  the  divorc^  between 
religious  theorylmd  eTOn^^i^  rp^jit^g  ..HaH  inng  b£g^  evi- 
dent. But  ill  the  meantime,  within  the  bosom  of  religious 
tlieuiyltself,  a  new  system  of  ideas  was  being  matured, 
which  was  destined  to  revolutionize  all  traditional  values, 
and  to  turn  on  the  whole  field  of  social  obligations  a  new 
and  penetrating  light.  On  a  world  heaving  with  expanding 
energies,  and  a  Church  uncertain  of  itself,  rose,  after  two 
generations  of  premonitory  mutterings,  the  tremendous 
storm  of  the  Puritan  movement.  The  forest  bent;  the  oaks 
snapped;  the  dry  leaves  were  driven  before  a  gale,  neither 
all  of  winter  nor  all  of  spring,  but  violent  and  life-giving, 
pitiless  and  tender,  sounding  strange  notes  of  yearning  and 
contrition,  as  of  voices  wrung  from  a  people  dwelling  in 
Meshec,  which  signifies  Prolonging,  in  Kedar,  which  signi- 
fies Blackness;  while  amid  the  blare  of  trumpets,  and  the 
clash  of  arms,  and  the  rending  of  the  carved  work  of  the 
Temple,  humble  to  God  and  hauty  to  man,  the  soldier-saints 
swept  over  battlefield  and  scaffold  their  garments  rolled  in 
blood. 

In  the  great  silence  which  fell  when  the  Titans  had  turned 
to  dust,  in  the  Augustan  calm  of  the  eighteenth  century,  a 
voice  was  heard  to  observe  that  religious  liberty  was  a  con- 
siderable advantage,  regarded  "merely  in  a  commercial 
view."  *  A  new  world,  it  was  evident,  had  arisen.  And  this 
new  world,  born  of  the  vision  of  the  mystic,  the  passion  of 
the  prophet,  the  sweat  and  agony  of  heroes  famous  and  un- 
known, as  well  as  of  mundane  ambitions  and  commonplace 
cupidities,  was  one  in  which,  since  "Thorough'7  was  no 
more,  since  property  was  secure,  and  contracts  inviolable, 
and  the  executive  tamed,  the  judicious  investments  of  busi- 
ness men  were  likely  to  wield  a  profitable  return.  So  the 
epitaph,  which  crowns  the  life  of  what  is  called  success, 
mocks  the  dreams  in  which  youth  hungered,  not  for  success, 
but  for  the  glorious  failure  of  the  martyr  or  the  saint. 

164 


PURITANISM   AND   SOCIETY  1<SS 

I.    PURITANISM  AND  SOCIETY 

The  principal  streams  which  descended  in  England  from 
the  teaching  of  Calvin  were  three — Presbyterianism,  Con- 
gregationalism, and  a  doctrine  of  the  nature  of  God  aiwl 
man,  which,  if  common  to  both,  was  more  widely  diffused, 
more  pervasive  and  more  potent  than  either.  Of  these  three 
off-shoots  from  the  parent  stem,  the  first  and  eldest,  which 
had  made  some  stir  under  Elizabeth,  and  which  it  was 
hoped,  with  judicious  watering  from  the  Scotch,  might  grow 
into  a  State  Church,  was  to  produce  a  credal  statement 
carved  in  bronze,  but  was  to  strike,  at  least  in  its  original 
guise,  but  slender  roots.  The  second,  with  its  insistence  on 
the  right  of  every  Church  to  organize  itself,  and  on  the  free- 
dom of  all  Churches  from  the  interference  of  the  State,  was 
to  leave,  alike  in  the  Old  World  and  in  the  New,  an  imper- 
ishable legacy  of  civil  and  religious  liberty.  The  third  was 
Puritanism  Straitened  to  no  single  sect,  and  represented  in' 
the  Anglican  Church  hardly,  if  at  all,  less  fully  than  in 
those  which  afterwards  separated  from  it,  it  determined,  not 
only  conceptions  of  theology  and  church  government,  but 
political  aspirations,  business  relations,  family  life  and  the 
minutiae  of  personal  behavior. 

The  growth,  triumph  and  transformatjnp  of  thfi  PuritAf> 
spirit  was  the  nmst  fqndamental  movement  of  the-seven- 
teentlTcentury.  Puritanism,  not  the  Tudor  secession  from 
RomeTwas  fEeTtrue  English  Reformation,  and  it  is  from  its 
struggle  against  the  old  order  that  an  England  which  is 
unmistakably  modern  emerges.  But,  immense  as  were  its 
accomplishments  on  the  higher  stage  of  public  affairs,  its 
achievements  in  that  inner  world,  of  which  politics  are  but 
the  squalid  scaffolding,  were  mightier  still  Like  an  iceberg, 
which  can  awe  the  traveller  by  its  towering  majesty  only 
because  sustained  by  a  vaster  mass  which  escapes  his  eye, 
the  revolution  which  Puritanism  wrought  in  Church  and 
State  was  less  than  that  which  it  worked  in  men's  souls,  and 
the  watchwords  which  it  thundered,  amid  the  hum  of  Par- 
liaments and  the  roar  of  battles,  had  been  learned  in  the 
lonely  nights,  when  Jacob  wrestled  with  the  angel  of  the 
Lord  to  wring  a  blessing  before  he  fled. 

We  do  it  wrong,  being  so  majestical 
To  offer  it  the  show  of  violence. 


166  THE   PURITAN   MOVEMENT 

In  the  mysticism  of  Bunyan  and  Fox,  in  the  brooding  mel- 
ancholy and  glowing  energy  of  Cromwell,  in  the  victorious 
tranquillity  of  Milton,  "unshaken,  unseduced,  un terrified," 
amid  a  world  of  self-seekers  and  apostates,  there  are  depths 
of  light  and  darkness  which  posterity  can  observe  with 
reverence  or  with  horror,  but  which  its  small  fathom-line 
cannot  plumb. 

There  are  types  of  character  which  are  like  a  prism,  whose 
various  and  brilliant  colors  are  but  broken  reflections  of  a 
single  ray  of  concentrated  light.  If  the  inward  and  spiritual 
grace  of  Puritanism  eludes  the  historian,  its  outward  and 
visible  signs  meet  him  at  every  turn,  and  not  less  in  market- 
place and  counting-house  and  camp  than  in  the  student's 
chamber  and  the  gathering  of  the  elect  for  prayer.  For  to 
the  Puritan,  a  contemner  of  the  vain  shows  of  saciamen- 
talism,  mundane  toil  becomes  itself  a  kind  of  sacrament.  Like 
a  man  who  strives  by  unresting  activity  to  exorcise  a  haunt- 
ing demon,  the  Puritan,  in  the  effort  to  save  his  own  soul, 
sets  in  motion  every  force  in  heaven  above  or  in  the  earth 
beneath.  By  the  mere  energy  of  his  expanding  spirit,  he 
remakes,  not  only  his  own  character  and  habits  and  way  of 
life,  but  family  and  church,  industry  and  city,  political  insti- 
tutions and  social  order.  Conscious  that  he  is  but  a  stranger 
and  pilgrim,  hurrying  from  this  transitory  life  to  a  life  to 
come,  he  turns  with  almost  physical  horror  from  the  vanities 
which  lull  into  an  awful  indifference  souls  dwelling  on  the 
borders  of  eternity,  to  pore  with  anguish  of  spirit  on  the 
grand  facts,  God,  the  soul,  starvation  and  damnation.  "It 
made  the  world  seem  to  me,"  said  a  Puritan  of  his  conver- 
sion, "as  a  carkass  that  had  neither  life  nor  loveliness.  And 
it  destroyed  those  ambitious  desires  after  literate  fame, 
which  was  the  sin  of  my  childhood.  ...  It  set  me  upon 
that  method  of  my  studies  which  since  then  I  have  found 
the  benefit  of.  ...  It  caused  me  first  to  seek  God's  King- 
dom and  his  Righteousness,  and  most  to  mind  the  One  thing 
needful,  and  to  determine  first  of  my  Ultimate  End."  2 

Overwhelmed  by  a  sense  of  his  "Ultimate  End,"  the 
Puritan  cannot  rest,  nevertheless,  in  reflection  upon  it.  The 
contemplation  of  God,  which  the  greatest  of  the  Schoolmen 
described  as  the  supreme  blessedness,  is  a  blessedness  too 
great  for  sinners,  who  must  not  only  contemplate  God,  but 
glorify  him  by  their  work  in  a  world  given  over  to  the  pow- 


PURITANISM  AND  SOCIETY  lfit 

ers  of  darkness.  "The  way  to  the  Celestial  City  lies  just 
through  this  town,  where  this  lusty  fair  is  kept;  and  he 
that  will  go  to  the  City,  and  yet  not  go  through  this  town, 
must  needs  go  out  of  the  world/' 3  For  that  awful  journey, 
girt  with  precipices  and  beset  with  fiends,  he  sheds  every 
encumbrance,  and  arms  himself  with  every  weapon.  Amuse- 
ments, books,  even  intercourse  with  friends,  must,  if  need 
be,  be  cast  aside;  for  it  is  better  to  enter  into  eternal  life 
halt  and  maimed  than  having  two  eyes  to  be  cast  into  eter- 
nal fire.  He  scours  the  country,  like  Baxter  and  Fox,  to  find 
one  who  may  speak  the  word  of  life  to  his  soul.  He  seeks 
from  his  ministers,  not  absolution,  but  instruction,  exhorta- 
tion and  warning.  Prophesyings — that  most  revealing  episode 
in  early  Puritanism — were  the  cry  of  a  famished  generation 
for  enlightenment,  for  education,  for  a  religion  of  the  intel- 
lect; and  it  was  because  much  "preaching  breeds  faction, 
but  much  praying  causes  devotion"  4  that  the  powers  of  this, 
world  raised  their  parchment  shutters  to  stem  the  gale  that 
blew  from  the  Puritan  pulipt.  He  disciplines,  rationalizes, 
systematizes,  his  life;  "method"  was  a  Puritan  catchword  a 
century  before  the  world  had  heard  of  Methodists.  He  makes 
his  very  business  a  travail  of  the  spirit,  for  that  too  is  the 
Lord's  vineyard,  in  which  he  is  called  to  labor. 

Feeling  in  him  that  which  "maketh  him  more  fearful  of 
displeasing  God  than  all  the  world,"  r>  he  is  a  natural  repub- 
lican, for  there  is  none  on  earth  that  he  can  own  as  master. 
If  powers  and  principalities  will  hear  and  obey,  well;  if  not, 
they  must  be  ground  into  dust,  that  on  their  ruins  the  elect 
may  build  the  Kingdom  of  Christ.  And,  in  the  end,  all  these 
— prayer,  and  toil,  and  discipline,  mastery  of  self  and  mas- 
tery of  others,  wounds,  and  death — may  be  too  little  for  the 
salvation  of  a  single  soul.  "Then  I  saw  that  there  was  a  way 
to  Hell  even  from  the  Gates  of  Heaven,  as  well  as  from  the 
City  of  Destruction"  6 — those  dreadful  words  haunt  him  as 
he  nears  his  end.  Sometimes  they  break  his  heart.  More 
often,  for  grace  abounds  even  to  the  chief  of  sinners,  they 
nerve  his  will.  For  it  is  will — will  organized  and  disciplined 
and  inspired,  will  quiescent  in  rapt  adoration  or  straining  in 
violent  energy,  but  always  will — which  is  the  essence  of 
Puritanism,  and  for  the  intensification  and  organization  of 
will  every  instrument  in  that  tremendous  arsenal  of  religious 
fervour  is  mobilized.  The  Puritan  is  like  a  steel  spring  com- 


168  THE   PURITAN   MOVEMENT 

pressed  by  an  inner  force,  which  shatters  every  obstacle  by 
its  rebound.  Sometimes  the  strain  is  too  tense,  and,  when 
its  imprisoned  energy  is  released,  it  shatters  itself. 

The  spirit  bloweth  where  it  listeth,  and  men  of  every  so- 
cial grade  had  felt  their  hearts  lifted  by  its  breath,  from 
aristocrats  and  country  gentlemen  to  weavers  who,  "as  they 
stand  in  their  loom,  can  set  a  book  before  them  or  edifie 
one  another."  7  But,  if  religious  zeal  and  moral  enthusiasm 
are  not  straitened  by  the  vulgar  categories  of  class  and  in- 
come, experience  proves,  nevertheless,  that  there  are  certain 
kinds  of  environment  in  which  they  burn  more  bravely  than 
in  others,  and  that,  as  man  is  both  spirit  and  body,  so  dif- 
ferent types  of  religious  experience  correspond  to  the  vary- 
ing needs  of  different  social  and  economic  milieux.  To 
contemporaries  the  chosen  seat  of  the  Puritan  spirit  seemed 
to  be  those  classes  in  society  which  combined  economic  inde- 
pendence, education  and  a  certain  decent  pride  in  their 
status,  revealed  at  once  in  a  determination  to  live  their  own 
lives,  without  truckling  to  earthly  superiors,  and  in  a  some- 
what arrogant  contempt  for  those  who,  either  through  weak- 
ness of  character  or  through  economic  helplessness,  were  less 
resolute,  less  vigorous  and  masterful,  than  themselves.  Such, 
where  the  feudal  spirit  had  been  weakened  by  contact  with 
town  life  and  new  intellectual  currents,  were  some  of  the 
gentry.  Such,  conspicuously,  were  the  yeomen,  "mounted  on 
a  high  spirit,  as  being  slaves  to  none,"  8  especially  in  the 
freeholding  counties  of  the  east.  Such,  above  all,  were  the 
trading  classes  of  the  towns,  and  of  those  rural  districts 
which  had  been  partially  industrialized  by  the  decentraliza- 
tion of  the  textile  and  iron  industries. 

"The  King's  cause  and  party,"  wrote  one  who  described 
the  situation  in  Bristol  in  1645,  "were  favored  by  two  ex- 
tremes in  that  city;  the  one,  the  wealthy  and  powerful  men, 
the  other,  of  the  basest  and  lowest  sort;  but  disgusted  by 
the  middle  rank,  the  true  and  best  citizens  " 9  That  it  was 
everywhere  these  classes  who  were  the  standard-bearers  of 
Puritanism  is  suggested  by  Professor  Usher's  statistical  es- 
timate of  the  distribution  of  Puritan  ministers  in  the  first 
decade  of  the  seventeenth  century,  which  shows  that,  of  281 
ministers  whose  names  are  known,  35  belonged  to  London 
and  Middlesex,  96  to  the  three  manufacturing  counties  of 
Norfolk,  Suffolk  and  Essex,  29  to  Northamptonshire,  17  to 


PURITANISM   AND   SOCIETY  169 

Lancashire,  and  only  104  to  the  whole  of  the  rest  of  the 
country.10  The  phenomenon  was  so  striking  as  to  evoke  the 
comments  of  contemporaries  absorbed  in  matters  of  pro- 
founder  spiritual  import  than  sociological  generalization. 
"Most  of  the  tenants  of  these  gentlemen,"  wrote  Baxter, 
"and  also  most  of  the  poorest  of  the  people,  whom  the  other 
called  the  Rabble,  did  follow  the  gentry,  and  were  for  the 
King.  On  the  Parliament's  side  were  (besides  themselves) 
the  smaller  part  (as  some  thought)  of  the  gentry  in  most  of 
the  counties,  and  freeholders,  and  the  middle  sort  of  men; 
especially  in  those  corporations  and  counties  which  depend 
on  cloathing  and  such  manufactures."  He  explained  the  fact 
by  the  liberalizing  effect  of  constant  correspondence  with 
the  greater  centers  of  trade,  and  cited  the  example  of  France, 
where  it  was  "the  merchants  and  middle  sort  of  men  that 
were  Protestants."  u 

The  most  conspicuous  example  was,  of  course,  London, 
which  had  financed  the  Parliamentary  forces,  and  which 
continued  down  to  the  Revolution  to  be  par  excellence  "the 
rebellious  city,"  returning  four  Dissenters  to  the  Royalist 
Parliament  of  1661,  sending  its  mayor  and  aldermen  to  ac- 
company Lord  Russell  when  he  carried  the  Exclusion  Bill 
from  the  Commons  to  the  Lords,  patronizing  Presbyterian 
ministers  long  after  Presbyterianism  was  proscribed,  nursing 
the  Whig  Party,  which  stood  for  tolerance,  and  sheltering 
the  Whig  leaders  against  the  storm  which  broke  in  1681. 
But  almost  everywhere,  the  same  fact  was  to  be  observed. 
The  growth  of  Puritanism,  wrote  a  hostile  critic,  was  "by 
meanes  of  the  City  of  London  (the  nest  and  seminary  of  the 
seditious  faction)  and  by  reason  of  its  universall  trade 
throughout  the  kingdome,  with  its  commodities  conveying 
and  deriving  this  civill  contagion  to  all  our  cities  and  cor- 
porations, and  thereby  poysoning  whole  counties." 12  In 
Lancashire,  the  clothing  towns — "the  Genevas  of  Lanca- 
shire"— rose  like  Puritan  islands  from  the  surrounding  sea 
of  Roman  Catholicism.  In  Yorkshire,  Bradford,  Leeds  and 
Halifax;  in  the  midlands,  Birmingham  and  Leicester;  in  the 
west,  Gloucester,  Taunton  and  Exeter,  the  capital  of  the 
west  of  England  textile  industry,  were  all  centers  of  Puri- 
tanism. 

The  identification  of  the  industrial  and  commercial  classes 
with  religious  radicalism  was,  indeed,  a  constant  theme  of 


170  THE  PURITAN  MOVEMENT 

Anglicans  and  Royalists,  who  found  in  the  vices  of  each  an 
additional  reason  for  distrusting  both.  Clarendon  commented 
bitterly  on  the  "  factious  humor  which  possessed  most  cor- 
porations, and  the  pride  of  their  wealth";13  and,  after  the 
Civil  War,  both  the  politics  and  the  religion  of  the  boroughs 
were  suspect  for  a  generation.  The  bishop  of  Oxford  warned 
Charles  II 's  Government  against  showing  them  any  favor, 
on  the  ground  that  "trading  combinations"  were  "so  many 
nests  of  faction  and  sedition,"  and  that  "our  late  miserable 
distractions"  were  "chiefly  hatched  in  the  shops  of  trades- 
men." 14  Pepys  commented  dryly  on  the  black  looks  which 
met  the  Anglican  clergy  as  they  returned  to  their  City 
"Churches.  It  was  even  alleged  that  the  courtiers  hailed  with 
glee  the  fire  of  London,  as  a  providential  instrument  for 
crippling  the  center  of  disaffection.15 

When,  after  1660,  Political  Arithmetic  became  the  fash- 
ion, its  practitioners  were  moved  by  the  experience  of  the 
last  half-century  and  by  the  example  of  Holland — the  eco- 
nomic schoolmaster  of  seventeenth-century  Europe — to  in- 
quire, in  the  manner  of  any  modern  sociologist,  into  the  re- 
lations between  economic  progress  and  other  aspects  of  the 
national  genius.  Cool,  dispassionate,  very  weary  of  the  drum 
ecclesiastic,  they  confirmed,  not  without  some  notes  of  gentle 
irony,  the  diagnosis  of  bishop  and  presbyterian,  but  deduced 
from  it  different  conclusions.  The  question  which  gave  a 
topical  point  to  their  analysis  was  the  rising  issue  of  reli- 
gious tolerance.  Serenely  indifferent  to  its  spiritual  signifi- 
cance, they  found  a  practical  reason  for  applauding  it  in  the 
fact  that  the  classes  who  were  in  the  van  of  the  Puritan 
movement,  and  in  whom  the  Clarendon  Code  found  its  most 
prominent  victims,  were  also  those  who  led  commercial  and 
industrial  enterprise.  The  explanation,  they  thought,  was 
simple.  A  society  of  peasants  could  be  homogeneous  in  its 
religion,  as  it  was  already  homogeneous  in  the  simple  uni- 
formity of  its  economic  arrangements.  A  many-sided  business 
community  could  escape  constant  friction  and  obstruction 
only  if  it  were  free  to  absorb  elements  drawn  from  a  multi- 
tude of  different  sources,  and  if  each  of  those  elements  were 
free  to  pursue  its  own  way  of  life,  and — in  that  age  the 
same  thing — to  practice  its  own  religion. 

Englishmen,  as  Defoe  remarked,  improved  everything  and 
invented  nothing,  and  English  economic  organization  had 


PURITANISM   AND   SOCIETY  171 

long  been  elastic  enough  to  swallow  Flemish  weavers  flying 
from  Alva,  and  Huguenots  driven  from  France.  But  the 
traditional  ecclesiastical  system  was  not  equally  accomodat- 
ing.  It  found  not  only  the  alien  refugee,  but  its  homebred 
sectaries,  indigestible.  Laud,  reversing  the  policy  of  Eliza- 
bethan Privy  Councils,  which  characteristically  thought 
diversity  of  trades  more  important  than  unity  of  religion, 
had  harassed  the  settlements  of  foreign  artisans  at  Maid- 
stone,  Sandwich  and  Canterbury,10  and  the  problem  recurred 
in  every  attempt  to  enforce  conformity  down  to  1689.  "The 
gaols  were  crowded  with  the  most  substantial  tradesmen 
and  inhabitants,  the  clothiers  were  forced  from  their  houses, 
and  thousands  of  workmen  and  women  whom  they  employed 
set  to  starving."  1T  The  Whig  indictment  of  the  disastrous 
effects  of  Tory  policy  recalls  the  picture  drawn  by  French 
intendants  of  the  widespread  distress  which  followed  the 
revocation  of  the  Edict  of  Nantes.18 

When  the  collision  between  economic  interests  and  the 
policy  of  compulsory  conformity  was  so  flagrant,  it  is  not 
surprising  that  the  economists  of  the  age  should  have  enun- 
ciated the  healing  principle  that  persecution  was  incompat- 
ible with  prosperity,  since  it  was  on  the  pioneers  of  economic 
progress  that  persecution  principally  fell.  "Every  law  of 
this  nature/7  wrote  the  author  of  a  pamphlet  on  the  subject, 
is  not  only  " expressly  against  the  very  principles  of  rules 
of  the  Gospel  of  Christ,"  but  is  also  "destructive  to  the  trade 
and  well-being  of  our  nation  by  oppressing  and  driving  away 
the  most  industrious  working  hands,  and  depopulating,  and 
thereby  impoverishes  our  country,  which  is  capable  of  em- 
ploying ten  times  the  number  of  people  we  now  have." 19 

Temple,  in  his  calm  and  lucid  study  of  the  United  Neth- 
erlands, found  one  reason  of  their  success  in  the  fact  that, 
Roman  Catholicism  excepted,  every  man  might  practise  what 
religion  he  pleased.20  De  la  Court,  whose  striking  book 
passed  under  the  name  of  John  de  Witt,  said  the  same.21 
Petty,  after  pointing  out  that  in  England  the  most  thriving 
towns  were  those  where  there  was  most  nonconformity, 
cited  the  evidence,  not  only  of  Europe,  but  of  India  and  the 
Ottoman  Empire,  to  prove  that,  while  economic  progress  is 
compatible  with  any  religion,  the  class  which  is  its  vehicle 
will  always  consist  of  the  heterodox  minority,  who  "profess 
opinions  different  from  what  are  publicly  established."22 


172  THK   PURITAN   MOVEMENT 

"There  is  a  kind  of  natural  unaptness,"  wrote  a  pamphlet- 
eer in  1671,  uin  the  Popish  religion  to  business,  whereas  on 
the  contrary  among  the  Reformed,  the  greater  their  zeal, 
the  greater  their  inclination  to  trade  and  industry,  as  hold- 
ing idleness  unlawful.  .  .  .  The  domestic  interest  of  England 
lieth  in  the  advancement  of  trade  by  removing  all  obstruc- 
tions both  in  city  and  country,  and  providing  such  laws  as 
may  help  it,  and  make  it  most  easy,  especially  in  giving 
liberty  of  conscience  to  all  Protestant  Nonconformists,  and 
denying  it  to  Papists."  23 

If  the  economists  applauded  tolerance  because  it  was  good 
for  trade,  the  Tory  distrust  of  the  commercial  classes  was 
aggravated  by  the  fact  that  it  was  they  who  were  most  vocal 
in  the  demand  for  tolerance.  Swift  denounced,  as  part  of  the 
settle  odious  creed,  the  maxim  that  "religion  ought  to  make 
no  distinctien  between  Protestants"  and  the  policy  "of  pre- 
ferring, on  all  occasions,  the  monied  interests  before  the 
landed."24  Even  later  in  the  eighteenth  century,  the  stale 
gibe  of  "the  Presbyterians,  the  Bank  and  the  other  corpora- 
tions" still  figured  in  the  pamphlets  of  the  statements  whom 
Lord  Morley  describes  as  the  prince  of  political  charlatans, 
Bolingbroke.25 

"The  middle  ranks,"  "the  middle  class  of  men,"  "the 
middle  sort" — such  social  strata  included,  of  course,  the 
widest  variety  of  economic  interest  and  personal  position. 
But  in  the  formative  period  of  Puritanism,  before  the  Civil 
War,  two  causes  prevented  the  phrase  from  being  merely  the 
vapid  substitute  for  thought  which  it  is  today.  In  the  first 
place,  outside  certain  exceptional  industries  and  districts, 
there  was  little  large-scale  production  and  no  massed  prole- 
tariat of  propertyless  wage-earners.  As  a  result,  the  typical 
workman  was  still  normally  a  small  master,  who  continued 
himself  to  work  at  the  loom  or  at  the  forge,  and  whose 
position  was  that  described  in  Baxter's  Kidderminster,  where 
"there  were  none  of  the  tradesmen  very  rich  .  .  .  the  magis- 
trates of  the  town  were  few  of  them  worth  £40  per  annum, 
and  most  not  half  so  much;  three  or  four  of  the  richest 
thriving  masters  of  the  trade  got  but  about  £500  to  ^600 
in  twenty  years,  and  it  may  be  lost  £100  of  it  at  once  by 
an  ill  debtor."  26  Differing  in  wealth  from  the  prosperous 
merchant  or  clothier,  such  men  resembled  them  in  economic 
and  social  habits,  and  the  distinction  between  them  was 


PURITANISM  AND  SOCIETY  173 

one  of  degree,  not  of  kind.  In  the  world  of  industry  vertical 
divisions  between  district  and  district  still  cut  deeper  than 
horizontal  fissures  between  class  and  class.  The  number  of 
those  who  could  reasonably  be  described  as  independent, 
since  they  owned  their  own  tools  and  controlled  their  own 
business,  formed  a  far  larger  proportion  of  the  population 
than  is  the  case  in  capitalist  societies. 

The  second  fact  was  even  more  decisive.  The  business 
classes,  as  a  power  in  the  State,  were  still  sufficiently  yoking 
to  be  conscious  of  themselves  as  something  like  a  separate 
order,  with  an  outlook  on  religion  and  politics  peculiarly 
their  own,  distinguished,  not  merely  by  birth  and  breeding, 
but  by  their  social  habits,  their  business  discipline,  the  whole 
bracing  atmosphere  of  their  moral  life,  from  a  Court  which 
they  believed  to  be  godless  and  an  aristocracy  which  they 
knew  to  be  spendthrift.  The  estrangement — for  it  was  no 
more — was  of  shorter  duration  in  England  than  in  any  other 
European  country,  except  Switzerland  and  Holland.  By  the 
latter  part  of  the  seventeenth  century,  partly  as  a  result  of 
the  common  struggles  which  made  the  Revolution,  still  more 
perhaps  through  the  redistribution  of  wealth  by  commerce 
and  finance,  the  former  rivals  were  on  the  way  to  be  com- 
pounded in  the  gilded  clay  of  a  plutocracy  embracing  both. 
The  landed  gentry  were  increasingly  sending  their  sons  into 
business;  "the  tradesman  meek  and  much  a  liar"  looked 
forward,  as  a  matter  of  course,  to  buying  an  estate  from  a 
bankrupt  noble.  Georgian  England  was  to  astonish  foreign 
observers,  like  Voltaire  and  Montesquieu,  as  the  Paradise 
of  the  bourgeoisie,  in  which  the  prosperous  merchant  shoul- 
dered easily  aside  the  impoverished  bearers  of  aristocratic 
names.27 

That  consummation,  however,  was  subsequent  to  the  great 
divide  of  the  Civil  War,  and,  in  the  main,  to  the  tamer 
glories  of  the  Revolution.  In  the  germinating  period  of  Puri- 
tanism, the  commercial  classes,  though  powerful,  were  not 
yet  the  dominant  force  which  a  century  later  they  were  to 
become.  They  could  look  back  on  a  not  distant  past,  in 
which  their  swift  rise  to  prosperity  had  been  regarded  with 
suspicion,  as  the  emergence  of  an  alien  interest,  which  ap- 
plied sordid  means  to  the  pursuit  of  anti-social  ends — an 
interest  for  which  in  a  well-ordered  commonwealth  there 
was  little  room,  and  which  had  been  rapped  on  the  knuckles 


174  THE   PURITAN   MOVEMENT 

by  conservative  statesmen.  They  lived  in  a  present,  where  a 
Government,  at  once  interfering,  inefficient  and  extravagant, 
cultivated,  with  an  intolerable  iteration  of  grandiloquent 
principles,  every  shift  and  artifice  most  repugnant  to  the 
sober  prudence  of  plain-dealing  men.  The  less  reputable 
courtiers  and  the  more  feather-pated  provincial  gentry,  while 
courting  them  to  raise  a  mortgage  or  renew  a  loan,  reviled 
them  as  parvenus,  usurers  and  blood-suckers.  Even  in  the 
latter  part  of  the  seventeenth  century,  the  influence  of  the 
rentier  and  of  the  financier  still  continued  to  cause  appre- 
hension and  jealousy,  both  for  political  and  for  economic 
reasons.  "By  this  single  stratagem,"  wrote  an  indignant 
pamphleteer  of  the  Puritan  capitalists  who  specialized  in 
money-lending,  "they  avoyd  all  contributions  of  tithes  and 
taxes  to  the  King,  Church,  Poor  (a  soverain  cordial  to  ten- 
der consciences) ;  they  decline  all  services  and  offices  of 
burthen  incident  to  visible  estates;  they  escape  all  oaths 
and  ties  of  publick  allegiance  or  private  fealty.  .  .  .  They 
enjoy  both  the  secular  applause  of  prudent  conduct,  and 
withal  the  spiritual  comfort  of  thriving  easily  and  devoutly 
.  .  .  leaving  their  adversaries  the  censures  of  improvidence, 
together  with  the  misery  of  d<*cay.  They  keep  many  of  the 
nobility  and  gentry  in  perfect  vassalage  (as  their  poor  copy- 
holders), which  eclipses  honour,  enervates  justice  and  oft- 
times  protects  them  in  their  boldest  conceptions.  By  en- 
grossing cash  and  credit,  they  in  effect  give  the  price  to  land 
and  law  to  markets.  By  commanding  ready  money,  they 
likewise  command  such  offices  as  they  widely  affect  .  .  .  they 
feather  and  enlarge  their  own  nests,  the  corporations  " 2S 

Such  lamentations,  the  protest  of  senatorial  dignity  against 
equestrian  upstarts  or  of  the  noblesse  against  the  roturier, 
were  natural  in  a  conservative  aristocracy,  which  for  a  cen- 
tury had  felt  authority  and  prestige  slipping  from  its  grasp, 
and  which  could  only  maintain  its  hold  on  them  by  resign- 
ing itself,  as  ultimately  it  did,  to  sharing  them  with  its  rival. 
In  return,  the  business  world,  which  had  its  own  religious 
and  political  ideology,  steadily  gathered  the  realities  of 
power  into  its  own  hands;  asked  with  a  sneer,  "how  would 
merchants  thrive  if  gentlemen  would  not  be  unthriftes";29 
and  vented  the  indignant  contempt  felt  by  an  energetic,  suc- 
cessful and,  according  to  its  lights,  not  too  unscrupulous, 
generation  for  a  class  of  jaineants,  unversed  in  the  new 


PURITANISM  AND   SOCIETY  17§ 

learning  of  the  City  and  incompetent  to  the  verge  of  im- 
morality in  the  management  of  business  affairs.  Their  tri- 
umphs in  the  past,  their  strength  in  the  present,  their  con- 
fidence in  the  future,  their  faith  in  themselves,  and  their 
difference  from  their  feebler  neighbours — a  diffrence  as  of 
an  iron  wedge  in  a  lump  of  clay — made  them,  to  use  a  mod- 
ern phrase,  class-conscious.  Like  the  modern  proletarian, 
who  feels  that,  whatever  his  personal  misery  and  his  present 
disappointments,  the  Cause  is  rolled  forward  to  victory  by 
the  irresistible  force  of  an  inevitable  evolution,  the  Puritan 
bourgeoisie  knew  that  against  the  chosen  people  the  gates 
of  hell  could  not  prevail.  The  Lord  prospered  their  doings. 
There  is  a  magic  mirror  in  which  each  order  and  organ  of 
society,  as  the  consciousness  of  its  character  and  destiny 
dawns  upon  it,  looks  for  a  moment,  before  the  dust  of  con- 
flict or  the  glamour  of  success  obscures  its  vision.  In  that 
enchanted  glass,  it  sees  its  own  lineaments  reflected  with 
ravishing  allurements;  for  what  it  sees  is  not  what  it  is,  but 
what  in  the  eyes  of  mankind  and  of  its  own  heart  it  would 
be.  The  feudal  noblesse  had  looked,  and  had  caught  a 
glimpse  of  a  world  of  fealty  and  chivalry  and  honor.  The 
monarchy  looked,  or  Laud  and  Strafford  looked  for  if;  they 
saw  a  nation  drinking  the  blessings  of  material  prosperity 
and  spiritual  edification  from  the  cornucopia  of  a  sage  and 
paternal  monarchy — a  nation  "fortified  and  adorned  .  .  . 
the  country  rich  .  .  .  the  Church  flourishing  .  .  .  trade  in- 
creased to  that  degree  that  we  were  the  exchange  of  Chris- 
tendom ...  all  foreign  merchants  looking  upon  nothing  as 
their  own  but  what  they  laid  up  in  the  warehouses  of  this 
Kingdom."  30  In  a  far-off  day  the  craftsman  and  laborer 
were  to  look,  and  see  a  band  of  comrades,  where  fellowship 
should  be  known  for  life  and  lack  of  fellowship  for  death, 
For  the  middle  classes  of  the  early  seventeenth  century, 
rising  but  not  yet  triumphant,  that  enchanted  mirror  was 
Puritanism.  What  it  showed  was  a  picture  grave  to  stern- 
ness, yet  not  untouched  with  a  sober  exaltation — an  earnest, 
zealous,  godly  generation,  scorning  delights,  punctual  in 
labor,  constant  in  prayer,  thrifty  and  thriving,  filled  with  a 
decent  pride  in  themselves  and  their  calling,  assured  that 
strenuous  toil  is  acceptable  to  Heaven,  a  people  like  those 
Dutch  Calvinists  whose  economic  triumphs  were  as  famous 
as  their  iron  Protestantism — " thinking,  sober,  and  patient 


176  THE   PURITAN   MOVEMENT 

men,  and  such  as  believe  that  labor  and  industry  is  their 
duty  toward  God."  31  Then  an  air  stirred  and  the  glass  was 
dimmed.  It  was  long  before  any  questioned  it  again. 

II.    A  GODLY  DISCIPLINE  versus  THE  RELIGION  OF  TRADE 

Puritanism  was  the  schoolmaster  of  the  English  middle 
classes.  It  heightened  their  virtues,  sanctified,  without  erad- 
icating, their  convenient  vices,  and  gave  them  an  inexpug- 
nable assurance  that,  behind  virtues  and  vices  alike,  stood 
the  majestic  and  inexorable  laws  of  an  omnipotent  Provi- 
dence, without  whose  foreknowledge  not  a  hammer  could 
beat  upon  the  forge,  not  a  figure  could  be  ackied  to  the 
ledger.  But  it  is  a  strange  school  which  does  not  leach  more 
than  one  lesson,  and  the  social  reactions  of  Puritanism, 
trenchant,  permanent  and  profound,  are  not  to  be  summa- 
rized in  the  simple  formula  that  it  fostered  individualism. 
Weber,  in  a  celebrated  essay,  expounded  the  thesis  that 
Calvinism,  in  its  English  version,  was  the  parent  of  capital- 
ism, and  Troeltsch,  Schulze-Gaevernitz  and  Cunnigham 
have  lent  to  the  same  interpretation  the  weight  of  their 
considerable  authority.32  But  the  heart  of  man  holds  mys- 
teries of  contradiction  which  live  in  vigorous  incompatabil- 
ity  together.  When  the  shriveled  tissues  lie  in  our  hand,  the 
spiritual  bond  still  eludes  us. 

In  every  human  soul  there  is  a  socialist  and  an  individ- 
ualist, an  authoritarian  and  a  fanatic  for  liberty,  as  in  each 
there  is  a  Catholic  and  a  Protestant.  The  same  is  true  of  the 
mass  movements  in  which  men  marshal  themselves  for  com- 
mon action.  There  was  in  Puritanism  an  element  which  was 
conservative  and  traditionalist,  and  an  element  which  was 
revolutionary;  a  collectivism  which  grasped  at  an  iron  disci- 
pline, and  an  individualism  which  spurned  the  savorless 
mess  of  human  ordinances;  a  sober  prudence  which  would 
garner  the  fruits  of  this  world,  and  a  divine  recklessness 
which  would  make  all  things  new.  For  long  nourished  to- 
gether, their  discords  concealed,  in  the  furnace  of  the  Civil 
War  they  fell  apart,  and  Presbyterian  and  Independent, 
aristocrat  and  Leveller,  politician  and  merchant  and  Utopian, 
gazed  with  bewildered  eyes  on  the  strange  monsters  with 
whom  they  had  walked  as  friends.  Then  the  splendors  and 
illusions  vanished;  the  force  of  common  things  prevailed; 


A   GODLY   DISCIPLINE  177 

the  metal  cooled  in  the  mould;  and  the  Puritan  spirit,  shorn 
of  its  splendors  and  its  illusions,  settled  finally  into  its  de- 
cent bed  of  equitable  respectability.  But  each  element  in  its 
social  philosophy  had  once  been  as  vital  as  the  other,  and 
the  battle  was  fought,  not  between  a  Puritanism  solid  for 
one  view  and  a  State  committed  to  another,  but  between 
rival  tendencies  in  the  soul  of  Puritanism  itself.  The  prob- 
lem is  to  grasp  their  connection,  and  to  understand  the  rea- 
sons which  caused  this  to  wax  and  that  to  wane 

"The  triumph  of  Puritanism,"  it  has  been  said,  "swept 
away  all  traces  of  any  restriction  or  guidance  in  the  em- 
ployment of  money."33  That  it  swept  away  the  restrictions 
imposed  by  the  existing  machinery  is  true;  neither  ecclesi- 
astical courts,  nor  High  Commission,  nor  Star  Chamber, 
could  function  after  1640.  But,  if  it  broke  the  discipline  of 
the  Church  of  Laud  and  the  State  of  Strafford,  it  did  so  but 
as  a  step  towards  erecting  a  more  rigorous  discipline  of  its 
own.  It  would  have  been  scandalized  by  economic  individual- 
ism as  much  as  by  religious  tolerance,  and  the  broad  outlines 
of  its  scheme  of  organization  favored  unrestricted  liberty  in 
matters  of  business  as  little  as  in  the  things  of  the  spirit. 
To  the  Puritan  of  any  period  in  the  century  between  the 
accession  of  Elizabeth  and  the  Civil  War,  the  suggestion  that 
he  was  the  friend  of  economic  or  social  license  would  have 
seemed  as  wildly  inappropriate  as  it  would  have  appeared 
to  most  of  his  critics,  who  taunted  him,  except  in  the  single 
matter  of  usury,  with  an  intolerable  meticulousness. 

A  godly  discipline  was,  indeed,  the  very  ark  of  the  Puritan 
covenant.  Delivered  in  thunder  to  the  Moses  of  Geneva,  its 
vital  necessity  had  been  the  theme  of  the  Joshuas  of  Scot- 
land, England  and  France.  Knox  produced  a  Scottish  edition 
of  it ;  Cart wright,  Travers  and  Udall  composed  treatises  ex- 
pounding it.  Bancroft  exposed  its  perils  for  the  established 
ecclesiastical  order.34  The  word  "discipline"  implied  essen* 
tially  "a  directory  of  Church  government,"  established  in 
order  that  "the  wicked  may  be  corrected  with  ecclesiastical 
censures,  according  to  the  quality  of  the  fault",35  and  the 
proceedings  of  Puritan  classes  in  the  sixteenth  century  show 
that  the  conception  of  a  rule  of  life,  to  be  enforced  by  the 
pressure  of  the  common  conscience,  and  in  the  last  resort 
by  spiritual  penalties,  was  a  vital  part  of  their  system. 
When-  at  the  beginning  of  Elizabeth's  reign,  the  sectaries  in 


178  THE   PURITAN    MOVEMENT 

London  described  their  objects  as  not  merely  the  "free  and 
pur*"  preaching  of  the  Gospel,  nor  the  pure  ministration  of 
the  sacraments,  but  "to  have,  not  the  fylthye  canon  lawe, 
but  disciplyne  onelye  and  altogether  agreeable  to  the  same 
heavenlye  and  Allmightye  word  of  our  good  Lorde  Jesus 
Chryste,"  ™  the  antithesis  suggests  that  something  more 
than  verbal  instruction  is  intended.  Bancroft  noted  that  it 
was  the  practice,  when  a  sin  was  committed  by  one  of  the 
faithful,  for  the  elders  to  apply  first  admonishment  and  then 
excommunication.  The  minute-book  of  one  of  the  few  classes 
whose  records  survive  confirms  his  statement  7 

All  this  early  movement  had  almost  flickered  out  before 
the  end  of  the  sixteenth  century.  But  the  conception  lay  at 
the  very  root  of  Presbyterianism,  and  it  reemerged  in  the 
system  of  church  government  which  the  supercilious  Scotch 
Commissioners  at  the  Westminster  Assembly  steered  to  in- 
conclusive victory,  between  Erastians  on  the  right  and 
Independents  on  the  left.  The  destruction  of  the  Court  of 
High  Commission,  of  the  temporal  jurisdiction  of  all  persons 
in  Holy  Orders,  and  finally,  with  the  abolition  of  episcopacy, 
of  the  ecclesiastical  courts  themselves,  left  a  vacuum.  "Mr. 
Henderson,"  wrote  the  insufferable  Baillie,  "has  ready  now 
a  short  treatise,  much  called  for,  of  our  church  discipline."  3fi 
In  June  1646  an  unenthusiastic  Parliament  accepted  the 
ordinance  which,  after  a  three  years'  debate  of  intolerable 
tedium,  emerged  from  the  Assembly's  Committee  on  the 
Discipline  and  Government  of  the  Church,  and  which  pro- 
vided for  the  suspension  by  the  elders  of  persons  guilty  of 
scandalous  offences.  Detested  by  the  Independents  and 
cold-shouldered  by  Parliament,  which  had  no  intention  of 
admitting  the  divine  right  of  presbyteries,  the  system  never 
took  deep  root,  and  in  London,  at  least,  there  appears  to 
be  no  evidence  of  any  exercise  of  jurisdiction  by  elders  or 
classes.  In  parts  of  Lancashire,  on  the  other  hand,  it  seems 
to  have  been  actively  at  work,  down,  at  any  rate,  to  1649. 
The  change  in  the  political  situation,  in  particular  the  tri- 
umph of  the  army,  prevented  it,  Mr.  Shaw  thinks,  from 
functioning  longer.59 

"Discipline"  included  all  questions  of  moral  conduct,  and 
of  these,  in  an  age  when  a  great  mass  of  economic  relations 
were  not  the  almost  automatic  reactions  of  an  impersonal 
mechanism,  but  a  matter  of  human  kindliness  or  meanness 


A  GODLY  DISCIPLINE  179 

between  neighbors  in  village  or  borough,  economic  conduct 
was  naturally  part.  Calvin  and  Beza,  perpetuating  with  a 
new  intensity  the  medieval  idea  of  a  Church-civilization,  had 
sought  to  make  Geneva  a  pattern,  not  only  of  doctrinal 
purity,  but  of  social  righteousness  and  commercial  morality. 
Those  who  had  drunk  from  their  spring  continued,  in  even 
less  promising  environments,  the  same  tradition.  Bucer,  who 
wrote  when  something  more  fundamental  than  a  politician's 
reformation  seemed  possible  to  enthusiasts  with  their  eyes 
on  Geneva,  had  urged  the  reconstruction  of  every  side  of 
the  economic  life  of  a  society  which  was  to  be  Church  and 
State  in  one.40  English  Puritanism,  while  accepting  after 
some  hesitation  Calvin's  much  qualified  condonation  of 
moderate  interest,  did  not  intend  in  other  respects  to  coun- 
tenance a  laxity  welcome  only  to  worldlings.  Knewstub  ap- 
pealed to  the  teaching  of  "that  worthy  instrument  of  God, 
Mr.  Calvin,"  to  prove  that  the  habitual  usurer  ought  to  be 
"thrust  out  of  the  society  of  men."  Smith  embroidered  the 
same  theme.  Baro,  whose  Puritanism  lost  him  his  professor- 
ship, denounced  the  "usual  practice  amongst  rich  men,  and 
some  of  the  greater  sort,  who  by  lending,  or  by  giving  out 
their  money  to  usury,  are  wont  to  snare  and  oppress  the 
poor  and  needier  sort."  Cartwright,  the  most  famous  leader 
of  Elizabethan  Puritanism,  described  usury  as  "a  hainous 
offence  against  God  and  his  Church,"  and  laid  down  that 
the  offender  should  be  excluded  from  the  sacraments  until 
he  satisfied  the  congregation  of  his  penitenance.41  The  ideal 
of  all  was  that  expressed  in  the  apostolic  injunction  to  be 
content  with  a  modest  competence  and  to  shun  the  allure- 
ments of  riches.  "Every  Christian  man  is  bound  in  conscience 
before  God,"  wrote  Stubbes,  "to  provide  for  his  household 
and  family,  but  yet  so  as  his  immoderate  care  surpasse  not 
the  bands,  nor  yet  transcend  the  limits,  of  true  Godlynes. 
...  So  farre  from  covetousnes  and  from  immoderate  care 
would  the  Lord  have  us,  that  we  ought  not  this  day  to  care 
for  tomorrow,  for  (saith  he)  sufficient  to  the  day  is  the 
travail  of  the  same."  42 

The  most  influential  work  on  social  ethics  written  in  the 
first  half  of  the  seventeenth  century  from  the  Puritan  stand- 
point was  Ames'  De  Conscientia,  a  manual  of  Christian  con- 
duct which  was  intended  to  supply  the  brethren  with  the 
practical  guidance  which  had  been  offered  in  the  Middle 


180  THE   PURITAN   MOVEMENT 

Ages  by  such  works  as  Dives  et  Pauper.  It  became  a  stand- 
ard authority,  quoted  again  and  again  by  subsequent  writers. 
Forbidden  to  preach  by  the  bishop  of  London,  Ames  spent 
more  than  twenty  years  in  Holland,  where  he  held  a  chair 
of  theology  at  the  University  of  Franeker,  and  his  experi- 
ence of  social  life  in  the  country  which  was  then  the  business 
capital  of  Europe  makes  the  remorseless  rigor  of  his  social 
doctrine  the  more  remarkable.  He  accepts,  as  in  his  day  was 
inevitable,  the  impossibility  of  distinguishing  between  inter- 
est on  capital  invested  in  business,  and  interest  on  capital 
invested  in  land,  since  men  put  money  indifferently  into 
both,  and,  like  Calvin,  he  denies  that  interest  is  forbidden 
in  principle  by  Scripture  or  natural  reason.  But,  like  Calvin, 
he  surrounds  his  indulgence  with  qualifications ;  he  requires 
that  no  interest  shall  be  charged  on  loans  to  the  needy,  and 
describes  as  the  ideal  investment  for  Christians  one  in  which 
the  lender  shares  risks  with  the  borrower,  and  demands  only 
"a  fair  share  of  the  profits,  according  to  the  degree  in  which 
God  has  blessed  him  by  whom  the  money  is  used."  His 
teaching  with  regard  to  prices  is  not  less  conservative  "To 
wish  to  buy  cheap  and  to  sell  dear  is  common  (as  Augustine 
observes),  but  it  is  a  common  vice."  Men  must  not  sell 
above  the  maximum  fixed  by  public  authority,  though  they 
may  sell  below  it,  since  it  is  fixed  to  protect  the  buyer; 
when  there  is  no  legal  maximum,  they  must  follow  the  mar- 
ket price  and  "the  judgment  of  prudent  and  good  men." 
They  must  not  take  advantage  of  the  necessities  of  individ- 
ual buyers,  must  not  overpraise  their  wares,  must  not  sell 
them  dearer  merely  because  they  have  cost  them  much  to 
get.43  Puritan  utterances  on  the  subject  of  enclosing  were 
equally  trenchant.44 

Nor  was  such  teaching  merely  the  pious  pedantry  of  the 
pulpit.  It  found  some  echo  in  contrite  spirits;  it  left  some 
imprint  on  the  conduct  of  congregations.  If  D'Ewes  was  the 
unresisting  victim  of  a  more  than  ordinarily  aggressive  con- 
science, he  was  also  a  man  of  the  world  who  played  a  not 
inconspicuous  part  in  public  affairs;  and  D'Ewes  not  only 
ascribed  the  fire  which  destroyed  his  father's  house  to  the 
judgment  of  Heaven  on  ill-gotten  gains,  but  expressly  pre- 
scribed in  his  will  that,  in  order  to  avoid  the  taint  of  the 
accursed  thing,  provision  should  be  made  for  his  daughters, 
not  by  investing  his  capital  at  a  fixed — and  therefore  usuri- 


A   GODLY  DISCIPLINE  181 

ous — rate  of  interest,  but  by  the  purchase  either  of  land  or 
of  annuities.45  The  classis  which  met  at  Dedham  in  the 
eighties  of  the  sixteenth  century  was  concerned  partly  with 
questions  of  ceremony,  of  church  government,  of  the  right 
use  of  Sunday,  and  with  the  weighty  problems  whether  boys 
of  sixteen  might  wear  their  hats  in  church,  and  by  what 
marks  one  might  detect  a  witch.  But  it  discussed  also  what 
provision  could  be  made  to  check  vagrancy;  advised  the 
brethren  to  confine  their  dealings  to  "the  godliest  of  that 
trade"  (of  cloth  making) ;  recommended  the  establishment 
in  the  township  of  a  scheme  of  universal  education,  that  of 
children  of  parents  too  poor  to  meet  the  cost  being  defrayed 
from  collections  made  in  church;  and  urged  that  each  well- 
to-do  householder  should  provide  in  his  home  for  two  (or, 
if  less  able,  one)  of  his  impoverished  neighbors  who  "walke 
christianly  and  honestlie  in  their  callinges."  46  In  the  ever- 
lengthening  list  of  scandalous  and  notorious  sins  to  be  pun- 
ished by  exclusion  from  the  sacrament,  which  was  elaborated 
by  the  Westminster  Assembly,  a  place  was  found,  not  only 
for  drunkards,  swearers,  and  blasphemers,  worshippers  and 
makers  of  images,  senders  or  carriers  of  challenges,  persons 
dancing,  gaming,  attending  plays  on  the  Lord's  day,  or  re- 
sorting to  witches,  wizards  and  fortune-tellers,  but  for  the 
more  vulgar  vices  of  those  who  fell  into  extortion,  barratry 
and  bribery.47  The  classis  of  Bury  in  Lancashire  (quantum 
mutatusl)  took  these  economic  lapses  seriously.  It  decided 
in  1647,  after  considerable  debate,  that  "usury  is  a  scandal- 
ous sin,  deserving  suspention  upon  obstinacy."  48 

It  was  a  moment  when  good  men  were  agog  to  cast  the 
money-changers  from  the  temple  and  to  make  straight  the 
way  of  the  Lord.  "God  hath  honnored  you  in  callinge  you 
to  a  place  of  power  and  trust,  and  hee  expects  that  you 
should  bee  faith  full  to  that  trust.  You  are  postinge  to  the 
grave  every  day;  you  dwell  upon  the  borders  of  eternity; 
your  breath  is  in  your  nostrells;  therfore  duble  and  treble 
your  resolutions  to  bee  zealous  in  a  good  thinge.  .  .  .  How 
dreadful  will  a  dieinge  bed  bee  to  a  negligent  magistrate! 
What  is  the  reward  of  a  slothfull  servant?  Is  it  not  to  bee 
punished  with  everlastinge  destruction  from  the  presence  of 
the  Lord?"49  Such,  in  that  singular  age,  was  the  language 
in  which  the  mayor  of  Salisbury  requested  the  justices  of 


182  THE   PURITAN   MOVEMENT 

Wiltshire  to  close  four  public-houses.  Apparently  they  closed 
them. 

The  attempt  to  crystallize  social  morality  in  an  objective 
discipline  was  possible  only  in  a  theocracy;  and,  still  elo- 
quent in  speech,  theocracy  had  abdicated  in  fact,  even  before 
the  sons  of  Belial  returned  to  cut  down  its  groves  and  lay 
waste  its  holy  places.  In  an  age  when  the  right  to  dissent 
from  the  State  Church  was  still  not  fully  established,  its 
defeat  was  fortunate,  for  it  was  the  victory  of  tolerance.  It 
meant,  however,  that  the  discipline  of  the  Church  gave  place 
to  the  attempt  to  promote  reform  through  the  action  of  the 
State,  which  reached  its  height  in  the  Barebones  Parliament. 
Projects  for  law  reform,  marriage  reform  and  financial  re- 
form, the  reform  of  prisons  and  the  relief  of  debtors,  jostled 
each  other  on  its  committees;  while  outside  it  there  were 
murmurs  among  radicals  against  social  and  economic  priv- 
ilege, which  were  not  to  be  heard  again  till  the  days  of  the 
Chartists,  and  which  to  the  conservative  mind  of  Cromwell 
seemed  to  portend  mere  anarchy.  The  transition  from  the 
idea  of  a  moral  code  enforced  by  the  Church,  which  had 
been  characteristic  of  early  Calvinism,  to  the  economic  in- 
dividualism of  the  later  Puritan  movement  took  place,  in 
fact,  by  way  of  the  democratic  agitation  of  the  Independents 
Abhorring  the  whole  mechanism  of  ecclesiastical  discipline 
and  compulsory  conformity,  they  endeavored  to  achieve  the 
same  social  and  ethical  ends  by  political  action. 

The  change  was  momentous.  If  the  English  Social  Demo- 
cratic movement  has  any  single  source,  that  source  is  to  be 
found  in  the  New  Model  Army.  But  the  conception  implied 
in  the  attempt  to  formulate  a  scheme  of  economic  ethics — 
the  theory  that  every  department  of  life  falls  beneath  the 
same  all-encompassing  arch  of  religion — was  too  deeply  root- 
ted  to  be  exorcised  merely  by  political  changes,  or  even  by 
the  more  corroding  march  of  economic  development.  Ex- 
pelled from  the  world  of  fact,  where  it  had  always  been  a 
stranger  and  a  sojourner,  it  survived  in  the  world  of  ideas, 
and  its  champions  in  the  last  half  of  the  century  labored  it 
the  more,  precisely  because  they  knew  that  it  must  be  con- 
veyed to  their  audiences  by  teaching  and  preaching  or  not 
at  all.  Of  those  champions  the  most  learned,  the  most  prac- 
tical, and  the  most  persuasive  was  Richard  Baxter. 

How  Baxter  endeavored  to  give  practical  instruction  to 


A   GODLY   DISCIPLINE  183 

his  congregation  at  Kidderminster,  he  himself  has  told  us. 
" Every  Thursday  evening  my  neighbours  that  were  most 
desirous  and  had  opportunity  met  at  my  house,  and  there 
one  of  them  repeated  the  sermon,  and  afterwards  they  pro- 
posed what  doubts  any  of  them  had  about  the  sermon,  or 
anv  other  case  of  conscience,  and  1  resolved  their  doubts."  50 
Both  in  foim  and  in  matter,  his  Christian  Dhectory,  or  a 
Summ  of  Practical  Theologie  and  Cases  of  Conscience51  is 
a  remarkable  book.  It  is,  in  essence,  a  Puritan  Summ  a  The- 
ologtca  and  Summa  Mordis  in  one,  its  method  of  treatment 
descends  directly  from  that  of  the  medieval  Swnmae,  and  it 
is,  perhaps,  the  last  important  English  specimen  of  a  famous 
genus.  Its  object,  as  Baxter  explains  in  his  introduction,  is 
"the  resolving  of  practical  cases  of  conscience,  and  the  re- 
ducing of  theoretical  knowledge  into  serious  Christian  prac- 
tice." Divided  into  four  parts,  Ethics,  Economics,  Ecclesi- 
astics, and  Politics,  it  has  as  its  purpose  to  establish  the 
rules  of  a  Christian  casuistry,  which  may  be  sufficiently  de- 
tailed and  precise  to  afford  practical  guidance  to  the  proper 
conduct  of  men  in  the  different  relations  of  life,  as  lawyer, 
physician,  schoolmaster,  soldier,  master  and  servant,  buyer 
and  seller,  landlord  and  tenant,  lender  and  borrower,  ruler 
and  subject  Part  of  its  material  is  derived  from  the  treat- 
ment of  similar  questions  by  previous  writers,  both  before 
and  after  the  Reformation,  and  Baxter  is  conscious  of  con- 
tinuing a  great  tradition  But  it  is,  above  all  things,  realis- 
tic, and  its  method  lends  plausibility  to  the  suggestion  that 
it  originated  in  an  attempt  to  answer  practical  questions  put 
to  its  author  by  members  of  his  congregation.  Its  aim  is  not 
to  overwhelm  by  authority,  but  to  convince  by  an  appeal  to 
the  enlightened  common  sense  of  the  Christian  reader.  It 
does  not  overlook,  therefore,  the  practical  facts  of  a  world 
in  which  commerce  is  carried  on  by  the  East  India  Company 
in  distant  markets,  trade  is  universally  conducted  on  credit, 
the  iron  manufacture  is  a  large-scale  industry  demanding 
abundant  supplies  of  capital  and  offering  a  profitable  open- 
ing to  the  judicious  investor,  and  the  relations  of  landlords 
and  tenants  have  been  thrown  into  confusion  by  the  fire  of 
London.  Nor  does  it  ignore  the  moral  qualities  for  the  cul- 
tivation of  which  an  opportunity  is  offered  by  the  life  of 
business.  It  takes  as  its  starting-point  the  commercial  en- 


184  THE   PURITAN   MOVEMENT 

vironment  of  the  Restoration,  and  its  teaching  is  designed 
for  "Rome  or  London,  not  Fools'  Paradise." 

Baxter's  acceptance  of  the  realities  of  his  age  makes  the 
content  of  his  teaching  the  more  impressive.  The  attempt  to 
formulate  a  casuistry  of  economic  conduct  obviously  implies 
that  economic  relations  are  to  be  regarded  merely  as  one 
department  of  human  behavior,  for  which  each  man  is  mor- 
ally responsible,  not  as  the  result  of  an  impersonal  mech- 
anism, to  which  ethical  judgments  are  irrelevant.  Baxter 
declines,  therefore,  to  admit  the  convenient  dualism,  which 
exonerates  the  individual  by  representing  his  actions  as  the 
outcome  of  uncontrollable  forces.  The  Christian,  he  insists, 
is  committed  by  his  faith  to  the  acceptance  of  certain  ethical 
standards,  and  these  standards  are  as  obligatory  in  the  sphere 
of  economic  transactions  as  in  any  other  province  of  human 
activity.  To  the  conventional  objection  that  religion  has 
nothing  to  do  with  business — that  "every  man  will  get  as 
much  as  he  can  have  and  that  caveat  emptor  is  the  only 
security" — he  answers  bluntly  that  this  way  of  dealing  does 
not  hold  among  Christians.  Whatever  the  laxity  of  the  law, 
the  Christian  is  bound  to  consider  first  the  golden  rule  and 
the  public  good.  Naturally,  therefore,  he  is  debarred  from 
making  money  at  the  expense  of  other  persons,  and  certain 
profitable  avenues  of  commerce  are  closed  to  him  at  the 
outset.  "It  is  not  lawful  to  take  up  or  keep  up  any  oppress- 
ing monopoly  or  trade,  which  tends  to  enrich  you  by  the 
loss  of  the  Commonwealth  or  of  many." 

But  the  Christian  must  not  only  eschew  the  obvious  extor- 
tion practiced  by  the  monopolist,  the  engrosser,  the  organizer 
of  a  corner  or  a  combine.  He  must  carry  on  his  business 
in  the  spirit  of  one  who  is  conducting  a  public  service;  he 
must  order  it  for  the  advantage  of  his  neighbor  as  much  as, 
and,  if  his  neighbor  be  poor,  more  than,  for  his  own.  He 
must  not  desire  "to  get  another's  goods  or  labour  for  less 
than  it  is  worth."  He  must  not  secure  a  good  price  for  his 
own  wares  "by  extortion  working  upon  men's  ignorance, 
error,  or  necessity."  When  prices  are  fixed  by  law,  he  must 
strictly  observe  the  legal  maximum;  when  they  are  not,  he 
must  follow  the  price  fixed  by  common  estimation.  If  he  finds 
a  buyer  who  is  willing  to  give  him  more,  he  "must  not  make 
too  great  an  advantage  of  his  convenence  or  desire,  but  be 
glad  that  fhe]  can  pleasure  him  upon  equal,  fair,  and  honest 


A   GODLY  DISCIPLINE  185 

terms/'  for  "it  is  a  false  rule  of  them  that  think  their  com- 
modity is  worth  as  much  as  any  one  will  give."  If  the  seller 
forsees  that  in  the  future  prices  are  likely  to  fall,  he  must 
not  make  profit  out  of  his  neighbour's  ignorance,  but  must 
tell  him  so.  If  he  forsees  that  they  will  rise,  he  may  hold 
his  wares  back,  but  only — a  somewhat  embarrassing  excep- 
tion— if  it  be  not  "to  the  hurt  of  the  Commonwealth,  as  if 
.  .  .  keeping  it  in  be  the  cause  of  the  dearth,  and  .  .  .  bring- 
ing it  forth  would  help  to  prevent  it."  If  he  is  buying  from 
the  poor,  "charity  must  be  exercised  as  well  as  justice"; 
the  buyer  must  pay  the  full  price  that  the  goods  are  worth 
to  himself,  and,  rather  than  let  the  seller  suffer  because  he 
cannot  stand  out  for  his  price,  should  offer  him  a  loan  or 
persuade  some  one  else  to  do  so.  In  no  case  may  a  man 
doctor  his  wares  in  order  to  get  for  them  a  higher  price  than 
they  are  really  worth,  and  in  no  case  may  he  conceal  any 
defects  of  quality;  if  he  was  so  unlucky  as  to  have  bought 
an  inferior  article,  he  "may  not  repair  [his]  loss  by  doing 
as  [he  |  was  done  by,  ...  no  more  than  [he]  may  cut 
another's  purse  because  [his]  was  cut."  Rivalry  in  trade, 
Baxter  thinks,  is  inevitable  But  the  Christian  must  not 
snatch  a  good  bargain  "out  of  greedy  covetousness,  nor  to 
the  injury  of  the  poor  .  .  .  nor  ...  so  as  to  disturb  that 
due  and  civil  order  which  should  be  among  moderate  men 
in  trading."  On  the  contrary,  if  "a  covetous  oppressor" 
offer  a  poor  man  less  than  his  goods  are  worth,  "it  may  be 
a  duty  to  offer  the  poor  man  the  worth  of  his  commodity 
and  save  him  from  the  oppressor." 

The  principles  which  should  determine  the  contract  be- 
tween buyer  and  seller  are  applied  equally  to  all  other 
economic  relations.  Usury,  in  the  sense  of  payment  for  a 
loan,  is  not  in  itself  unlawful  for  Christians.  But  it  becomes 
so,  when  the  lender  does  not  allow  the  borrower  "such  a 
proportion  of  the  gain  as  his  labour,  hazard,  or  poverty  doth 
require,  but  .  .  .  will  live  at  ease  upon  his  labours";  or  when, 
in  spite  of  the  borrower's  misfortune,  he  rigorously  exacts 
his  pound  of  flesh;  or  when  interest  is  demanded  for  a  loan 
which  charity  would  require  to  be  free.  Masters  must  disci- 
pline their  servants  for  their  good;  but  it  is  "an  odious 
oppression  and  injustice  to  defraud  a  servant  or  labourer  of 
his  wages,  yea,  or  to  give  him  less  than  he  deserveth."  As 
the  descendant  of  a  family  of  yeomen,  "free,"  as  he  says, 


186  THE  PURITAN   MOVEMENT 

"from  the  temptations  of  poverty  and  riches," 52  Baxter  had 
naturally  strong  views  as  to  the  ethics  of  land-owning.  Sig- 
nificantly enough,  he  deals  with  them  under  the  general 
rubric  of  "Cases  of  oppression,  especially  of  tenants,"  op- 
pression being  defined  as  the  "injuring  of  inferiors  who  are 
unable  to  resist  or  to  right  themselves."  "It  is  too  common 
a  sort  of  oppression  for  the  rich  in  all  places  to  domineer 
too  insolently  over  the  poor,  and  force  them  to  follow  their 
wills  and  to  serve  their  interest,  be  it  right  or  wrong.  .  .  . 
Especially  unmerciful  landlords  are  the  common  and  sore 
oppressors  of  the  countrymen.  If  a  few  men  can  but  get 
money  enough  to  purchase  all  the  land  in  a  country,  they 
think  that  they  may  do  with  their  own  as  they  list,  and  set 
such  hard  bargains  of  it  to  their  tenants,  that  they  are  all 
but  as  their  servants.  ...  An  oppressor  is  an  Anti-Christ 
and  an  Anti-God  ...  not  only  the  agent  of  the  Devil,  but 
his  image."  As  in  his  discussion  of  prices,  the  gist  of  Bax- 
ter's analysis  of  the  cases  of  conscience  which  arise  in  the 
relations  of  landlord  and  tenant  is  that  no  man  may  secure 
pecuniary  gain  for  himself  by  injuring  his  neighbor.  Except 
in  unusual  circumstances,  a  landlord  must  not  let  his  land 
at  the  full  competitive  rent  which  it  would  fetch  in  the  mar- 
ket: "Ordinarily  the  common  sort  of  tenants  in  England 
should  have  so  much  abated  of  the  fullest  worth  that  they 
may  comfortably  live  on  it,  and  follow  their  labours  with 
cheerfulness  of  mind  and  liberty  to  serve  God  in  their  fam- 
ilies, and  to  mind  the  matters  of  their  salvation,  and  not  to 
be  necessitated  to  such  toil  and  care  and  pinching  want  as 
shall  make  them  liker  slaves  than  free  men."  He  must  not 
improve  (i.e.,  enclose)  his  land  without  considering  the  ef- 
fect on  the  tenants,  or  evict  his  tenants  without  compen- 
sating them,  and  in  such  a  way  as  to  cause  depopulation; 
nor  must  a  newcomer  take  a  holding  over  the  sitting  ten- 
ant's head  by  offering  "a  greater  rent  than  he  can  give  or 
than  the  landlord  hath  just  cause  to  require  of  him."  The 
Christian,  in  short,  while  eschewing  "causeless,  perplexing, 
melancholy  scruples,  which  would  stop  a  man  in  the  course 
of  his  duty,"  must  so  manage  his  business  as  to  "avoid  sin 
rather  than  loss,"  and  seek  first  to  keep  his  conscience  in 
peace. 

The  first  characteristic  to  strike  the  modern  reader  in  all 
this  teaching  is  its  conservatism.  In  spite  of  the  economic 


A   GODLY   DISCIPLINE  187 

and  political  revolutions  of  the  past  two  centuries,  how  small, 
after  all,  the  change  in  the  presentation  of  the  social  ethics 
of  the  Christian  faith!  A  few  months  after  the  appearance 
of  the  Christian  Directory,  the  Stop  of  the  Exchequer  tore 
a  hole  in  the  already  intricate  web  of  London  finance,  and 
.sent  a  shiver  through  the  money-markets  of  Europe.  But 
Baxter,  though  no  mere  antiquarian,  discourses  of  equity  in 
bargaining,  of  just  prices,  of  reasonable  rents,  of  the  sin  of 
usury,  in  the  same  tone,  if  not  with  quite  the  same  conclu- 
sions, as  a  medieval  Schoolman,  and  he  differs  from  one  of 
the  later  Doctors,  like  St.  Antomno,  hardly  more  than  St. 
Antonino  himself  had  differed  from  Aquinas  Seven  years 
later  Bunyan  published  The  Life  and  Death  of  MJ  .  Badman. 
Among  the  vices  which  it  pilloried  were  the  sin  of  extortion, 
"most  commonly  committed  by  men  of  trade,  who  without 
all  conscience,  when  they  have  an  advantage,  will  make  a 
prey  of  their  neighbour,"  the  covetousness  of  "hucksters, 
that  buy  up  the  poor  man's  victual  wholesale  and  sell  it  to 
him  again  for  unreasonable  gains,"  the  avarice  of  usurers, 
who  watch  till  "the  poor  fail  into  their  mouths,"  and  "of 
those  vile  wretches  called  pawn-brokers,  that  lend  money 
and  goods  to  poor  people,  who  are  by  necessity  forced  to 
such  an  inconvenience,  and  will  make  by  one  trick  or  an- 
other the  interest  of  what  they  so  lend  amount  to  thirty  and 
forty,  yea,  sometimes  fifty  pounds  by  the  year  "  As  Christian 
and  Christiana  watched  Mr.  Badman  thus  bite  and  pinch 
the  poor  in  his  shop  in  Bedford,  before  they  took  staff  and 
scrip  for  their  journey  to  a  more  distant  City,  they  remem- 
bered that  the  Lord  himself  will  plead  the  cause  of  the 
afflicted  against  them  that  oppress  them,  and  reflected, 
taught  by  the  dealings  of  Ephron  the  son  of  Zohar,  and 
of  David  with  Ormon  the  Jebusite,  that  there  is  a  "wicked- 
ness, as  in  selling  too  dear,  so  in  buying  too  cheap." 5a 
Brother  Berthold  of  Regensburg  had  said  the  same  foul 
centuries  before  in  his  racy  sermons  in  Germany.  The 
emergence  of  the  idea  that  "business  is  business,"  and  that 
the  world  of  commercial  transactions  is  a  closed  compart- 
ment with  laws  of  its  own,  if  more  ancient  than  is  often 
supposed,  did  not  win  so  plainless  a  triumph  as  is  sometimes 
suggested.  Puritan  as  well  as  Catholic  accepted  without 
demur  the  view  which  set  all  human  interests  and  activities 
within  the  compass  of  religion.  Puritans,  as  well  as  Cath- 


188  THE    PURITAN    MOVEMENT 

olics,  essayed  the  formidable  task  of  formulating  a  Christian 
casuistry  of  economic  conduct. 

They  essayed  it  But  they  succeeded  even  less  than  the 
Popes  and  Doctors  whose  teaching,  not  always  unwittingly, 
they  repeated.  And  their  failure  had  its  roots,  not  merely 
in  the  obstacles  offered  by  the  ever  more  recalcitrant  opposi- 
tion of  a  commercial  environment,  but,  like  all  failures  which 
are  significant,  in  the  soul  of  Puritanism  itself.  Virtues  are 
often  conquered  by  vices,  but  their  rout  is  most  complete 
when  it  is  inflicted  by  other  virtues,  more  militant,  more 
efficient,  or  more  congenial,  and  it  is  not  only  tares  which 
choke  the  ground  where  the  good  seed  is  sown  The  funda- 
mental question,  after  all,  is  not  what  kind  of  rules  a  faith 
enjoins,  but  what  type  of  character  it  esteems  and  cultivate5* 
To  the  scheme  of  Christian  ethics  which  offered  admonition* 
against  the  numberless  disguises  assumed  by  the  sin  which 
sticketh  fast  between  buying  and  selling,  the  Puritan  char- 
acter offered,  not  direct  opposition,  but  a  polished  surface 
on  which  these  irhnstlv  admonitions  ronVl  find  no  enduring 
foothold  The  rules  of  Christian  morality  elaborated  by  Bax- 
ter were  subtle  and  sincere  But  they  were  like  seeds  carried 
by  birds  from  a  distant  and  fertile  plain,  and  dropped  upon 
a  glacier  They  were  at  once  embalmed  and  sterilized  in  a 
river  of  ice 

"The  capitalist  «pint"  is  as  old  as  history,  and  was  not, 
as  has  sometimes  been  said,  the  offspring  of  Puritanism 
But  it  found  in  certain  aspects  of  later  Puritanism  a  tonic 
which  braced  its  energies  and  fortified  its  already  vigorous 
temper  At  first  sight,  no  contrast  could  be  more  violent  than 
that  between  the  iron  collectivism,  the  almost  military  disci- 
pline the  remorseless  and  violent  rigors  practiced  in  Calvin's 
Geneva,  and  preached  elsewhere  if  in  a  milder  form  by  his 
disciples,  and  the  impatient  rejection  of  all  traditional  re- 
strictions on  economic  enterprise  which  was  the  temper  of 
the  English  business  world  after  the  Civil  War  In  reality 
the  same  ingredients  were  present  throughout,  but  they  were 
mixed  in  chansms:  proportions,  and  exposed  to  different 
temperatures  at  different  times  Like  traits  of  individual 
character  which  are  suppressed  till  the  approach  of  maturity 
releases  them,  the  tendencies  in  Puritanism,  which  were  to 
make  it  later  a  potent  ally  of  the  movement  against  the 
control  of  economic  relations  in  the  name  either  of  social 


TRIUMPH    OF   THE   ECONOMIC   VIRTUES  189 

morality  or  o!  the  public  interest,  did  not  reveal  themselves 
till  political  and  economic  changes  had  prepared  a  congenial 
environment  for  their  growth.  Nor,  once  those  conditions 
were  created,  was  it  only  England  which  witnessed  the  trans- 
formation. In  all  countries  alike,  in  Holland,  in  America,  in 
Scotland,  in  Geneva  itself,  the  social  theory  of  Calvinism 
went  through  the  same  process  of  development.  It  had  begun 
by  being  the  very  soul  of  authoritarian  regimentation.  It 
ended  by  being  the  vehicle  for  an  almost  Utilitarian  in- 
dividualism While  social  reformers  in  the  sixteenth  century 
could  praise  Calvin  for  his  economic  rigor,  their  successors 
in  Restoration  England,  if  of  one  persuasion,  denounced  him 
as  the  parent  of  economic  license,  if  of  another,  applauded 
Calvinist  communities  for  their  commercial  enterprise  and 
for  their  freedom  from  antiquated  prejudices  on  the  subject 
of  economic  morality  So  little  do  those  who  shoot  the  arrows 
of  the  spirit  know  where  they  will  light. 

Ill     THE  TRIUMPH  OF  THE  ECONOMIC  VIRTUES 

"One  beam  in  a  dark  place,"  wrote  one  who  knew  the 
travail  of  the  spirit,  "hath  exceeding  much  refreshment  in  it. 
Blessed  be  His  name  for  shining  upon  so  dark  a  heart  as 
mine."  54  While  the  revelation  of  God  to  the  individual  soul 
is  the  center  of  all  religion,  the  essence  of  Puritan  theology 
was  that  it  made  it,  not  only  the  center,  but  the  whole  cir- 
cumference and  substance,  dismissing  as  dross  and  vanity 
all  else  but  this  secret  and  solitary  communion  Grace  alone 
can  save,  and  this  grace  is  the  direct  gift  of  God,  unmediated 
by  any  earthly  institution.  The  elect  cannot  by  any  act  of 
their  own  evoke  it;  but  they  can  prepare  their  hearts  to 
receive  it,  and  cherish  it  when  received  They  will  prepare 
them  best,  if  they  empty  them  of  all  that  may  disturb  the 
intentness  of  their  lonely  vigil.  Like  an  engineer,  who,  to 
canalize  the  rush  of  the  oncoming  tide,  dams  all  channels 
save  that  through  which  it  is  to  pour,  like  a  painter  who 
makes  light  visible  by  plunging  all  that  is  not  light  in  gloom, 
the  Puritan  attunes  his  heart  to  the  voice  from  Heaven  by 
an  immense  effort  of  concentration  and  abnegation  To  win 
all,  he  renounces  all.  When  earthly  props  have  been  cast 
down,  the  soul  stands  erect  in  the  presence  of  God.  Infinity 
is  attained  by  a  process  of  subtraction. 


190  THE    PURITAN    MOVEMENT 

To  a  vision  thus  absorbed  in  a  single  intense  experience, 
not  only  religious  and  ecclesiastical  systems,  but  the  entire 
world  of  human  relations,  the  whole  fabric  of  social  institu- 
tions, witnessing  in  all  the  wealth  of  their  idealism  and  their 
greed  to  the  infinite  creativeness  of  man,  reveal  themselves 
in  a  new  and  wintry  light.  The  fire  of  the  spirit  burns 
brightly  on  the  hearth;  but  through  the  windows  of  his  soul 
the  Puritan,  unless  a  poet  or  a  saint,  looks  on  a  landscape 
touched  by  no  breath  of  spring.  What  he  sees  is  a  forbidding 
and  frost-bound  wilderness,  rolling  its  snow-clad  leagues  to- 
wards the  grave — a  wilderness  to  be  subdued  with  aching 
limbs  beneath  solitary  stars.  Through  it  he  must  take  his 
way,  alone.  No  aid  can  avail  him.  no  preacher,  for  only  the 
elect  can  apprehend  with  the  spirit  the  word  of  God,  no 
Church,  for  to  the  visible  Church  even  reprobates  belong; 
no  sacrament,  for  sacraments  are  ordained  to  increase  the 
glory  of  God,  not  to  minister  spiritual  nourishment  to  man; 
hardly  God  himself,  for  Christ  died  for  the  elect,  and  it  may 
well  be  that  the  majesty  of  the  Creator  is  revealed  by  the 
eternal  damnation  of  all  but  a  remnant  of  the  created  V) 

His  life  is  that  of  a  soldier  in  hostile  territory  He  suffers 
in  spirit  the  perils  which  the  first  settlers  in  America  en- 
dured in  body,  the  sea  behind,  the  untamed  desert  in  front, 
a  cloud  of  inhuman  enemies  on  either  hand  Where  Catholic 
and  Anglican  had  caught  a  glimpse  of  the  invisible,  hovering 
like  a  consecration  over  the  gross  world  of  sense,  and  touch- 
ing its  muddy  vesture  with  the  unearthly  gleam  of  a  divine, 
yet  familiar,  beauty,  the  Puritan  mourned  for  a  lost  Para- 
dise and  a  creation  sunk  in  sin.  Where  they  had  seen  society 
as  a  mystical  body,  compact  of  members  varying  in  order 
and  degree,  but  dignified  by  participation  in  the  common 
life  of  Christendom,  he  saw  a  bleak  antithesis  between  the 
spirit  which  quickened  and  an  alien,  indifferent  or  hostile 
world.  Where  they  had  reverenced  the  decent  order  whereby 
past  was  knit  to  present,  and  man  to  man,  and  man  to  God, 
through  fellowship  in  works  of  charity,  in  festival  and  fast, 
in  the  prayers  and  ceremonies  of  the  Church,  he  turned  with 
horror  from  the  filthy  rags  of  human  righteousness.  Where 
they,  in  short,  had  found  comfort  in  a  sacrament,  he  started 
back  from  a  snare  set  to  entrap  his  soul. 

We  receive  but  what  we  give, 
And  in  our  life  alone  does  Nature  live 


TRIUMPH   OF   THE   ECONOMIC   VIRTUES  191 

Too  often,  contemning  the  external  order  as  unspiritual,  he 
made  it,  and  ultimately  himself,  less  spiritual  by  reason  of 
his  contempt. 

Those  who  seek  God  in  isolation  from  their  fellowmen, 
unless  trebly  armed  for  the  perils  of  the  quest,  are  apt  to 
find,  not  God,  but  a  devil,  whose  countenance  bears  an  em- 
barrassing resemblance  to  their  own  The  moral  self-suf- 
ficiency of  the  Puritan  nerved  his  will,  but  it  corroded  his 
sense  of  social  solidarity.  For,  if  each  individual  destiny 
hangs  on  a  private  transaction  between  himself  and  his 
Maker,  what  room  is  left  for  human  intervention?  A  serv- 
ant of  Jehovah  more  than  of  Christ,  he  revered  God  as  a 
Judge  rather  than  loved  him  as  a  Father,  and  was  moved 
less  by  compassion  for  his  erring  brethren  than  by  impatient 
indignation  at  the  blindness  of  vessels  of  wrath  who  usinned 
their  mercies."  A  spiritual  aristocrat,  who  sacrined  fraternity 
to  liberty,  he  drew  from  his  idealization  of  personal  respon- 
sibility a  theory  of  individual  rights,  which,  secularized  and 
generalized,  was  to  be  among  the  most  potent  explosives 
that  the  world  has  known.  He  drew  from  it  also  a  scale  of 
ethical  values,  in  which  the  traditional  scheme  of  Christian 
virtues  was  almost  exactly  reversed,  and  which,  since  he  was 
above  all  things  practical,  he  carried  as  a  dynamic  into  the 
routine  of  business  and  political  life. 

For,  since  conduct  and  action,  though  availing  nothing  to 
attain  the  free  gift  of  salvation,  are  a  proof  that  the  gift  has 
been  accorded,  what  is  rejected  as  a  means  is  resumed  as  a 
consequence,  and  the  Puritan  flings  himself  into  practical 
activities  with  the  daemonic  energy  of  one  who,  all  doubts 
allayed,  is  conscious  that  he  is  a  sealed  and  chosen  vessel. 
Once  engaged  in  affairs,  he  brings  to  them  both  the  qualities 
and  limitations  of  his  creed  in  all  their  remorseless  logic. 
Called  by  God  to  labor  in  his  vineyard,  he  has  within  him- 
self a  principle  at  once  of  energy  and  of  order,  which  makes 
him  h resistible  both  in  war  and  in  the  struggles  of  com- 
merce. Convinced  that  character  is  all  and  circumstances 
nothing,  he  sees  in  the  poverty  of  those  who  fall  by  the  way, 
not  a  misfortune  to  be  pitied  and  relieved,  but  a  moral  fail- 
ing to  be  condemned,  and  in  riches,  not  an  object  of  sus- 
picion— though  like  other  gifts  they  may  be  abused — but 
the  blessing  which  rewards  the  triumph  of  energy  and  will. 
Tempered  by  self-examination,  self-discipline,  self-control, 


192  THE    PURITAN    MOVEMENT 

he  is  the  practical  ascetic,  whose  victories  are  won  not  in 
the  cloister,  but  on  the  battlefield,  in  the  counting-house, 
and  in  the  market. 

This  temper,  of  course  with  infinite  varieties  of  quality 
and  emphasis,  found  its  social  organ  in  those  middle  and 
commercial  classes  who  were  the  citadel  of  the  Puritan 
spirit,  and  whom,  "ennobled  by  their  own  industry  and  vir- 
tue," 50  Milton  described  as  the  standard-bearers  of  progress 
and  enlightenment  We  are  so  accustomed  to  think  of  Eng- 
land as  par  excellence  the  pioneer  of  economic  progress,  that 
we  are  apt  to  forget  how  recently  that  role  has  been  as- 
sumed Tn  the  Middle  Ages  it  belonged  to  the  Italians,  in 
the  sixteenth  century  to  the  Netherland  dominions  of  the 
Spanish  Empire,  in  the  seventeenth  to  the  United  Provinces 
and,  above  all,  to  the  Dutch 

The  England  of  Shakespeare  and  ?>acon  was  still  largely 
medieval  in  its  economic  organization  and  social  outlook 
more  interested  in  maintaining  cu^omarv  standards  of  con- 
sumption than  in  accumulating  capital  for  future  production, 
with  an  aristocracy  contemptuous  of  the  economic  virtues, 
a  peasantry  farming  for  subsistence  amid  the  organized  con- 
fusion of  the  open-field  village,  and  a  small,  if  growing, 
body  of  jealously  conservative  craftsmen  Tn  such  a  society 
Puritanism  worked  like  the  yeast  which  sets  the  whole  mass 
fermenting  It  went  through  its  slack  and  loosely  knit  tex- 
ture like  a  troop  of  Cromwell's  Ironsides  through  the  dis- 
orderly cavalry  of  Rupert  Where,  as  in  Ireland,  the  elements 
were  so  alien  that  assimilation  was  out  of  the  question,  the 
result  was  a  wound  that  festered  for  three  centuries  Tn 
England  the  effect  was  that  at  once  of  an  irritant  and  of 
a  tonic.  Puritanism  had  its  own  standards  of  social  conduct, 
derived  partly  from  the  obvious  interests  of  the  commercial 
classes,  partly  from  its  conception  of  the  nature  of  God  and 
the  destiny  of  man  These  standards  were  in  sharp  antithesis, 
both  to  the  considerable  surviving  elements  of  feudalism  in 
English  society,  and  to  the  policy  of  the  authoritarian  State, 
with  its  ideal  of  an  ordered  and  graded  society,  whose  dif- 
ferent members  were  to  be  maintained  in  their  traditional 
status  by  the  pressure  and  protection  of  a  paternal  mon- 
archy. Sapping  the  former  by  its  influence  and  overthrowing 
the  latter  by  direct  attack,  Puritanism  became  a  potent 


TRIUMPH    OF    THE   ECONOMIC   VIRTUES  193 

force  in  preparing  the  way  for  the  commercial  civilization 
which  finally  triumphed  at  the  Revolution. 

The  complaint  that  religious  radicalism,  which  aimed  at 
upsetting  the  government  of  the  Church,  went  hand  in  hand 
with  an  economic  radicalism,  which  resented  the  restraints 
on  individual  self-interest  imposed  in  the  name  of  religion  or 
of  social  policy,  was  being  made  by  the  stricter  school  of  re- 
ligious opinion  quite  early  in  the  reign  of  Elizabeth. r>T  Sev- 
enteenth-century writers  repeated  the  charge  that  the  Pur- 
itan conscience  lost  its  delicacy  where  matters  of  business 
were  concerned,  and  some  of  them  were  sufficiently  struck 
by  the  phenomenon  to  attempt  an  historical  explanation  of 
it  The  example  on  which  they  usually  seized — the  symbol 
of  a  supposed  general  disposition  to  laxity — was  the  indul- 
gence shown  by  Puritan  divines  in  the  particular  matter  of 
moderate  interest  It  was  the  effect,  so  the  picturesque  story 
ran/'s  of  the  Marian  persecution  The  refugees  who  fled  the 
continent  could  not  start  business  in  a  foreign  country.  If, 
driven  by  necessity,  they  invested  their  capital  and  lived  on 
the  proceeds,  who  could  quarrel  with  so  venial  a  lapse  in  so 
good  a  cause?  Subsequent  writers  embellished  the  picture. 
The  redistribution  of  property  at  the  time  of  the  Dissolu- 
tion, and  the  expansion  of  trade  in  the  middle  of  the  century, 
had  led,  one  of  them  argued,  to  a  great  increase  in  the  vol- 
ume of  credit  transactions  The  opprobrium  which  attached 
to  loans  at  interest — "a  sly  and  forbid  practice11 — not  only 
among  Romanists  and  Anglicans,  but  among  honest  Puri- 
tans, played  into  the  hands  of  the  less  scrupulous  members 
of  "the  faction  "  Disappointed  in  politics,  they  took  to  mon- 
ey-lending, and,  without  venturing  to  justify  usury  in  the- 
ory, defended  it  in  practice  "Without  the  scandal  of  a  re- 
cantation, they  contrived  an  expedient,  by  maintaining  that, 
though  usury  for  the  name  were  stark  naught,  yet  for  wid- 
ows, orphans  and  other  impotents  (therein  principally  com- 
prising the  saints  under  persecution)  it  was  very  tolerable, 
because  profitable,  and  in  a  manner  necessary."  Naturally, 
Calvin's  doctrine  as  to  the  legitimacy  of  moderate  interest 
was  hailed  by  these  hypocrites  with  a  shout  of  glee  'Tt  took 
with  the  brethren  like  polygamy  with  the  Turks,  recom- 
mended by  the  example  of  divers  zealous  ministers,  who 
themselves  desired  to  pass  for  orphans  of  the  first  rank."  59 
Nor  was  it  only  as  the  apologist  of  moderate  interest  that 


194  THE   PURITAN   MOVEMENT 

Puritanism  was  alleged  to  reveal  the  cloven  hoof.  Puritans 
themselves  complained  of  a  mercilessness  in  driving  hard 
bargains,  and  of  a  harshness  to  the  poor,  which  contrasted 
unfavorably  with  the  practice  of  followers  of  the  unreformed 
religion.  "The  Papists,"  wrote  a  Puritan  in  1653,  "may  rise 
up  against  many  of  this  generation.  It  is  a  sad  thing  that  they 
should  be  more  forward  upon  a  bad  principle  than  a  Chris- 
tian upon  a  good  one  "  <}" 

Such,  in  all  ages,  is  history  as  seen  by  the  political  pam- 
phleteer. The  real  story  was  less  dramatic,  but  more  signifi- 
cant. From  the  very  beginning,  Calvinism  had  comprised 
two  elements,  which  Calvin  himself  had  fused,  but  which 
contained  the  seeds  of  future  discord.  It  had  at  once  given 
a  whole-hearted  imprimatur  to  the  life  of  business  enterprise, 
which  most  earlier  moralists  had  regarded  with  suspicion, 
and  had  laid  upon  it  the  restraining  hand  of  an  inquisitorial 
discipline.  At  Geneva,  where  Calvinism  was  the  creed  of  a 
small  and  homogeneous  city,  the  second  aspect  had  predom- 
inated; in  the  many-sided  life  of  England,  where  there  were 
numerous  conflicting  interests  to  balance  it,  and  where  it 
was  long  politically  weak,  the  first.  Then,  in  the  late  six- 
teenth and  early  seventeenth  centuries,  had  come  the  wave 
of  commercial  and  financial  expansion — companies,  colonies, 
capitalism  in  textiles,  capitalism  in  mining,  capitalism  in 
finance — on  the  crest  of  which  the  English  commercial 
classes,  in  Calvin's  day  still  held  in  leading-strings  by  con- 
servative statesmen,  had  climbed  to  a  position  of  dignity 
and  affluence. 

Naturally,  as  the  Puritan  movement  came  to  its  own, 
these  two  elements  flew  apart.  The  collectivism  half-commu- 
nistic aspect,  which  had  never  been  acclimatized  in  England, 
quietly  dropped  out  of  notice,  to  crop  up  once  more,  and  for 
the  last  time,  to  the  disgust  and  terror  of  merchant  and  land- 
owner, in  the  popular  agitation  under  the  Commonwealth. 
The  individualism  congenial  to  the  world  of  business  be- 
came the  distinctive  characteristic  of  a  Puritanism  which 
had  arrived,  and  which,  in  becoming  a  political  force,  was  at 
once  secularized  and  committed  to  a  career  of  compromise. 
Its  note  was  not  the  attempt  to  establish  on  earth  a  "King- 
dom of  Christ,"  but  an  ideal  of  personal  character  and  con- 
duct, to  be  realized  by  the  punctual  discharge  both  of  public 


TRIUMPH    OF   THE   ECONOMIC   VIRTUES  195 

and  private  duties.  Its  theory  had  been  discipline ;  its  prac- 
tical result  was  liberty. 

Given  the  social  and  political  conditions  of  England,  the 
transformation  was  inevitable.  The  incompatibility  of  Pres- 
byterianism  with  the  stratified  arrangement  of  English  so- 
ciety had  been  remarked  by  Hooker  (>1  Tf  the  City  Fathers 
of  Geneva  had  thrown  off  by  the  beginning  of  the  seventeenth 
century  the  religious  collectivism  of  Calvin's  regime,  it  was 
not  to  be  expected  that  the  landowners  and  bourgeoisie  of  an 
aristocratic  and  increasingly  commercial  nation,  however 
much  Calvinist  theology  might  appeal  to  them,  would  view 
with  favor  the  social  doctrines  implied  in  Calvinist  disci- 
pline. In  the  reign  of  the  first  two  Stuarts,  both  economic 
interests  and  political  theory  pulled  them  hard  in  the  oppo- 
site direction.  "Merchants'  doings,"  the  man  of  business  in 
Wilson's  Discourse  upon  Uusury  had  observed,  "must  not 
thus  be  overthwarted  by  preachers  and  others  that  cannot 
skill  of  their  dealings  "  (>J  Behind  the  elaborate  facade  of  Tu- 
dor State  control,  which  has  attracted  the  attention  of  his- 
torians, an  individualist  movement  had  been  steadily  devel- 
oping, which  found  expression  in  opposition  to  the  tradition- 
al policy  of  stereotyping  economic  relations  by  checking 
enclosure,  controlling  food  supplies  and  prices,  interfering 
with  the  money-market,  and  regulating  the  conditions  of 
the  wage  contract  and  of  apprenticeship.  In  the  first  forty 
years  of  the  seventeenth  century,  on  grounds  both  of  expe- 
diency and  of  principle,  the  commercial  and  propertied 
classes  were  becoming  increasingly  restive  undet  the  whole 
system,  at  once  ambitious  and  inefficient,  of  economic  pater- 
nalism It  was  in  the  same  sections  of  the  community  that 
both  religious  and  economic  dissatisfaction  were  most  acute. 
Puritanism,  with  its  idealization  of  the  spiritual  energies 
which  found  expression  in  the  activities  of  business  and  in- 
dustry, drew  the  isolated  rivulets  of  discontent  together,  and 
swept  them  forward  with  the  dignity  and  momentum  of  a 
religious  and  a  social  philosophy. 

For  it  was  not  merely  as  the  exponent  of  certain  tenets  as 
to  theology  and  church  government,  but  as  the  champion  of 
interests  and  opinions  embracing  every  side  of  the  life  of 
society,  that  the  Puritan  movement  came  into  collision  with 
the  Crown.  In  reality,  as  is  the  case  with  most  heroic  ideol- 
ogies, the  social  and  religious  aspects  of  Puritanism  were  not 


196  THE   PURITAN    MOVEMENT 

disentangled;  they  presented  themselves,  both  to  supporters 
and  opponents,  as  different  facets  of  a  single  scheme.  "All 
that  crossed  the  views  of  the  needy  courtiers,  the  proud  en- 
croaching priests,  the  thievish  projectors,  the  lewd  nobility 
and  gentry  .  .  .  whoever  could  endure  a  sermon,  modest  habit 
or  conversation,  or  anything  good — all  these  were  Puri- 
tans." <( '  The  clash  was  not  one  of  theories—  a  systematic  and 
theoretical  individualism  did  not  develop  till  after  the  Resto- 
ration— but  of  contradictory  economic  interests  and  incom- 
patible conceptions  of  social  expediency. 

The  economic  policy  haltingly  pursued  by  the  Government 
of  Charles  1  bore  some  resemblance  to  the  system  ot  which 
a  more  uncompromising  version  was  developed  between  1661 
and  1685  by  Colbert  in  France.  It  was  one  which  favored 
an  artificial  and  State-promoted  capitalism — a  capitalism 
resting  on  the  grant  of  privileges  and  concessions  to  com- 
pany promoters  who  would  pay  for  them,  and  accompanied 
by  an  elaborate  system  of  State  control,  which  again,  if 
partly  inspired  by  a  genuine  solicitude  for  the  public  inter- 
est, was  too  often  smeared  with  an  odious  trail  of  finance.  It 
found  its  characteristic  expression  in  the  grant  of  patents,  in 
the  revival  of  the  royal  monopoly  of  exchange  business, 
against  which  the  City  had  fought  under  Elizabeth,  in  at- 
tempts to  enforce  by  administrative  action  compliance  with 
the  elaborate  and  impracticable  code  controlling  the  textile 
trades  and  to  put  down  speculation  in  foodstuffs,  and  in 
raids  on  enclosing  landlords,  on  employers  who  paid  in  truck 
or  evaded  the  rates  fixed  by  assessment,  and  on  justices  who 
were  negligent  in  the  administration  of  the  Poor  Laws  Such 
measures  were  combined  with  occasional  plunges  into  even 
more  grandiose  schemes  for  the  establishment  of  county 
granaries,  for  taking  certain  industries  into  the  hands  of  the 
Crown,  and  even  for  the  virtual  nationalization  of  the  cloth 
manufacture."04 

"The  very  genius  of  that  nation  of  people,"  wrote  Strafford 
to  Laud  of  the  Puritans,  "leads  them  always  to  oppose,  as 
well  civilly  as  ecclesiastically,  all  that  ever  authority  or- 
dains for  them."  <ir>  Against  this  whole  attempt  to  convert 
economic  activity  into  an  instrument  of  profit  for  the  Gov- 
ernment and  its  hangers-on — against,  no  less,  the  spasmodic 
attempts  of  the  State  to  protect  peasants  against  landlords, 
craftsmen  against  merchants,  and  consumers  against  mid- 


TRIUMPH    OF    THE   ECONOMIC   VIRTUES  197 

dlemen — the  interests  which  it  thwarted  and  curbed  revolted 
with  increasing  pertinacity  Questions  of  taxation,  on  which 
attention  has  usually  been  concentrated,  were  in  reality 
merely  one  element  in  a  quarrel  which  had  its  deeper  cause 
in  the  collision  of  incompatible  social  philosophies.  The  Pur- 
itan tradesman  had  seen  his  business  ruined  by  a  monopoly 
granted  to  a  needy  courtier,  and  cursed  Laud  and  his  Pop- 
ish soap.  The  Puritan  goldsmith  or  financier  had  found  his 
trade  as  a  bullion-broker  hampered  by  the  reestablishment 
of  the  ancient  office  of  Royal  Exchanger,  and  secured  a  res- 
olution from  the  House  of  Commons,  declaring  that  the 
patent  vesting  it  in  Lord  Holland  and  the  proclamation  for- 
bidding the  exchanging  of  gold  and  silver  by  unauthorized 
persons  were  a  grievance.  The  Puritan  money-lender  had 
been  punished  by  the  Court  of  High  Commission,  and  railed 
at  the  interference  of  bishops  in  temporal  affairs.  The  Puri- 
tan clothier,  who  had  suffered  many  things  at  the  hands  of 
interfering  busy-bodies  despatched  from  Whitehall  to  teach 
him  his  business,  averted  discreet  eyes  when  the  Wiltshire 
workmen  threw  a  more  than  usually  obnoxious  Royal  Com- 
missioner into  the  Avon,  and,  when  the  Civil  War  came,  ral- 
lied to  the  Parliament  The  Puritan  country  gentleman  had 
been  harried  by  Depopulation  Commissions,  and  took  his 
revenge  with  the  meeting  of  the  Long  Parliament  The  Puri- 
tan merchant  had  seen  the  Crown  both  squeeze  money  out  of 
his  company,  and  threaten  its  monopoly  by  encouraging  in- 
terlopers to  infringe  its  charter.  The  Puritan  member  of  Par- 
liament had  invested  in  colonial  enterprises,  and  had  ideas 
as  to  commercial  policy  which  were  not  those  of  the  Govern- 
ment. Confident  in  their  own  energy  and  acumen,  proud  of 
their  success,  and  regarding  with  profound  distiust  the  in- 
terference both  of  Church  and  of  State  with  matters  of  busi- 
ness and  property  rights,  the  commercial  classes,  in  spite  of 
their  attachment  to  a  militant  mercantilism  in  matters  of 
trade,  were,  even  before  the  Civil  War,  more  than  half  con- 
verted to  the  administrative  nihilism  which  was  to  be  the 
rule  of  social  policy  in  the  century  following  ii  Their  de- 
mand was  the  one  which  is  usual  in  such  circumstances.  It 
was  that  business  affairs  should  be  left  to  be  settled  by  busi- 
ness men,  unhampered  by  the  intrusions  of  an  antiquated 
morality  or  by  misconceived  arguments  of  public  policy.66 
The  separation  of  economic  from  ethical  interests,  which 


198  THE   PURITAN    MOVEMENT 

was  the  note  of  all  this  movement,  was  in  sharp  opposition 
to  religious  tradition,  and  it  did  not  establish  itself  without 
a  struggle  Even  in  the  very  capital  of  European  commerce 
and  finance,  an  embittered  controversy  was  occasioned  by 
the  refusal  to  admit  usurers  to  communion  or  to  confer  de- 
grees upon  them;  it  was  only  after  a  storm  of  pamphleteer- 
ing, in  which  the  theological  faculty  of  the  University  of 
Utrecht  performed  prodigies  of  zeal  and  ingenuity,  that  the 
States  of  Holland  and  West  Friesland  closed  the  agitation 
by  declaring  that  the  Church  had  no  concern  with  questions 
of  banking  fl7  In  the  French  Calvinist  Churches,  the  decline 
of  discipline  had  caused  lamentations  a  generation  earlier.08 
In  America,  the  theocracy  of  Massachusetts,  merciless  alike 
to  religious  liberty  and  to  economic  license,  was  about  to  be 
undermined  by  the  rise  of  new  States  like  Rhode  Island  and 
Pennsylvania,  whose  tolerant,  individualist  and  utilitarian 
temper  was  destined  to  find  its  greatest  representative  in  the 
golden  common  sense  of  Benjamin  Franklin  (>q  'The  sin  of 
our  too  great  fondness  for  trade,  to  the  neglecting  of  our 
more  valuable  interests,"  wrote  a  Scottish  divine  in  1709, 
when  Glasgow  was  on  the  eve  of  a  triumphant  outburst  of 
commercial  enterprise,  "I  humbly  think  will  be  written  upon 
our  judgment  .  .  I  am  sure  the  Lord  is  remarkably  frown- 
ing upon  our  trade  .  .  .  since  it  was  put  in  the  room  of 
religion  "  7" 

In  England,  the  growing  disposition  to  apply  exclusively 
economic  standards  to  social  relations  evoked  from  Puritan 
writers  and  devmes  vigorous  protests  against  usurious  in- 
terest, extortionate  prices  and  the  oppression  of  tenants  by 
landlords.  The  faithful,  it  was  urged,  had  interpreted  only 
too  literally  the  doctrine  that  the  sinner  was  saved,  not  by 
works,  but  by  faith.  Usury,  uin  time  of  Popery  an  odious 
thing,"  n  had  become  a  scandal  Professors,  by  their  covei- 
ousness,  caused  the  enemies  of  the  reformed  religion  to  blas- 
pheme.72 The  exactions  of  the  forestaller  and  regrater  were 
never  so  monstrous  or  so  immune  from  interference.  The 
hearts  of  the  rich  were  never  so  hard,  nor  the  necessities  of 
the  poor  so  neglected.  'The  poor  able  to  work  are  suffered  to 
beg;  the  impotent,  aged  and  sick  are  not  sufficiently  provid- 
ed for,  but  almost  starved  with  the  allowance  of  3d.  and  4rf. 
a  piece  a  week.  .  .  .  These  are  the  last  times  indeed.  Men 


TRIUMPH    OF   THE   ECONOMIC   VIRTUES  199 

generally  are  all  for  themselves.  And  some  would  set  up  such, 
having  a  form  of  religion,  without  the  power  of  it.'' 7 ' 

These  utterances  came,  however,  from  that  part  of  the 
Puritan  mind  which  looked  backward.  That  which  looked 
forward  found  in  the  rapidly  growing  spirit  of  economic  en- 
terprise something  not  uncongenial  to  its  own  temper,  and 
went  out  to  welcome  it  as  an  ally.  What  in  Calvin  had  been 
a  qualified  concession  to  practical  exigencies  appeared  in 
some  of  his  later  followers  as  a  frank  idealization  of  the  life 
of  the  trader,  as  the  service  of  God  and  the  training-ground 
of  the  soul.  Discarding  the  suspicion  of  economic  motives, 
which  had  been  as  characteristic  of  the  reformers  as  of  me- 
dieval theologians,  Puritanism  in  its  later  phases  added  a 
halo  of  ethical  sanctification  to  the  appeal  of  economic  expe- 
diency, and  offered  a  moral  creed,  in  which  the  duties  of 
religion  and  the  calls  of  business  ended  their  long  estrange- 
ment in  an  unanticipated  reconciliation.  Its  spokesmen 
pointed  out,  it  is  true,  the  peril  to  the  sou!  involved  in  a 
single-minded  concentration  on  economic  interests.  The  en- 
emy, however,  was  not  riches,  but  the  bad  habits  sometimes 
associated  with  them,  and  its  warnings  against  an  excessive 
preoccupation  with  the  pursuit  of  gain  wore  more  and  more 
the  air  of  after-thoughts,  appended  to  teaching  the  main 
tendency  and  emphasis  of  which  were  little  affected  by  these 
incidental  qualifications.  It  insisted,  in  short,  that  money- 
making,  if  not  free  from  spiritual  dangers,  was  not  a  danger 
and  nothing  else,  but  that  it  could  be,  and  ought  to  be, 
carried  on  for  the  greater  glory  of  God 

The  conception  to  which  it  appealed  to  bridge  the  gulf 
sprang  from  the  very  heart  of  Puritan  theology.  It  was  that 
expressed  in  the  characteristic  and  oft-used  phrase,  "a  Call- 
ing." 74  The  rational  order  of  the  universe  is  the  work  of  God, 
and  its  plan  requires  that  the  individual  should  labor  for 
God's  glory.  There  is  a  spiritual  calling,  and  a  temporal 
calling.  It  is  the  first  duty  of  the  Christian  to  know  and  be- 
lieve in  God;  it  is  by  faith  that  he  will  be  saved.  But  faith 
is  not  a  mere  profession,  such  as  that  of  Talkative  of  Prat- 
ing Row,  whose  "religion  is  to  make  a  noise/7  The  only  gen- 
uine faith  is  the  faith  which  produces  works.  "At  the  day  of 
Doom  men  shall  be  judged  according  to  their  fruits.  It  will 
not  be  said  then,  Did  you  believe?  but,  Were  you  doers  or 
talkers  only?"  7r>  The  second  duty  of  the  Christian  is  to  labor 


200  THE   PURITAN    MOVEMENT 

in  the  affairs  of  practical  life,  and  this  second  duty  is  subor* 
dinate  only  to  the  first.  "God,"  wrote  a  Puritan  divine,  "doth 
call  every  man  and  woman  ...  to  serve  him  in  some  peculiar 
employment  in  this  world,  both  for  their  own  and  the  com- 
mon good.  .  .  .  The  Great  Governour  of  the  world  hath  ap- 
pointed to  every  man  his  proper  post  and  province,  and  let 
him  be  never  so  active  out  of  his  sphere,  he  will  be  at  a  great 
loss,  if  he  do  not  keep  his  own  vineyard  and  mind  his  own 
business."76 

From  this  reiterated  insistence  on  secular  obligations  as 
imposed  by  the  divine  will,  it  follows  that,  not  withdrawal 
from  the  world,  but  the  conscientious  discharge  of  the  du- 
ties of  business,  is  among  the  loftiest  of  religious  and  moral 
virtues.  "The  begging  friars  and  such  monks  as  live  only 
to  themselves  and  to  their  formal  devotion,  but  do  employ 
themselves  in  no  one  thing  to  further  their  own  subsistence 
or  the  good  of  mankind  .  .  .  yet  have  the  confidence  to 
boast  of  this  their  course  as  a  state  of  perfection;  which  in 
very  deed,  as  to  the  worthiness  of  it,  falls  short  of  the  poor- 
est cobbler,  for  his  is  a  calling  of  God,  and  theirs  is  none."77 
The  idea  was  not  a  new  one.  Luther  had  advanced  it  as  a 
weapon  against  monasticism.  But  for  Luther,  with  his  pa- 
triarchal outlook  on  economic  affairs,  the  calling  means  nor- 
mally that  slate  of  life  in  which  the  individual  has  been  set 
by  Heaven,  and  against  which  it  is  impiety  to  rebel.  On  the 
lips  of  Puritan  divines,  it  is  not  an  invitation  to  resignation, 
but  the  bugle-call  which  summons  the  elect  to  the  long  battle 
which  will  end  only  with  their  death.  "The  world  is  all  be- 
fore them."  They  are  to  hammer  out  their  salvation,  not 
merely  m  vo  cat  tone,  but  per  vocationcm.  The  calling  is  not 
a  condition  in  which  the  individual  is  born,  but  a  strenuous 
and  exacting  enterprise,  to  be  undertaken,  indeed,  under  the 
guidance  of  Providence,  but  to  be  chosen  by  each  man  for 
himself,  with  a  deep  sense  of  his  solemn  responsibilities 
"God  hath  given  to  man  reason  for  this  use,  that  he  should 
first  consider,  then  choose,  then  put  in  execution;  and  it  is 
a  preposterous  and  brutish  thing  to  fix  or  fall  upon  any 
weighty  business,  such  as  a  calling  or  condition  of  life,  with- 
out a  careful  pondering  it  in  the  balance  of  sound  reason  "  7S 

Laborare  cst  orare.  By  the  Puritan  moralist  the  ancient 
maxim  is  repeated  with  a  new  and  intenser  significance.  The 
labor  which  he  idealizes  is  not  simply  a  requirement  imposed 


TRIUMPH    OF   THE   ECONOMIC   VIRTUES  201 

by  nature,  or  a  punishment  for  the  sin  of  Adam.  It  is  itself  a 
kind  of  ascetic  discipline,  more  rigorous  than  that  demanded 
of  any  order  of  mendicants — a  discipline  imposed  by  the 
will  of  God,  and  to  be  undergone,  not  in  solitude,  but  in  the 
punctual  discharge  of  secular  duties.  It  is  not  merely  an  eco- 
nomic means,  to  be  laid  aside  when  physical  needs  have  been 
satisfied.  Jt  is  a  spiritual  end,  for  in  it  alone  can  the  soul 
find  health,  and  it  must  be  continued  as  an  ethical  duty  long 
after  it  has  ceased  to  be  a  material  necessity.  Work  thus 
conceived  stands  at  the  very  opposite  pole  from  "good 
works,"  as  they  were  understood,  or  misunderstood,  by  Prot- 
estants. They,  it  was  thought,  had  been  a  series  of  single 
transactions,  performed  as  compensation  for  particular  sins, 
or  out  of  anxiety  to  acquire  merit.  What  is  required  of  the 
Puritan  is  not  individual  meritorious  acts,  but  a  holy  life — a 
system  in  which  every  element  is  grouped  round  a  central 
idea,  the  service  of  God,  from  which  all  disturbing  irrele- 
vancies  have  been  pruned,  and  to  which  all  minor  interests 
are  subordinated. 

His  conception  of  that  life  was  expressed  in  the  words 
"Be  wholly  taken  up  in  diligent  business  of  your  lawful  call- 
ings, when  you  are  not  exercised  in  the  more  immediate  serv- 
ice of  God  "  ™  In  order  to  deepen  his  spiritual  life,  the 
Christian  must  be  prepared  to  narrow  it.  He  "is  blind  in  no 
man's  cause,  but  best  sighted  in  his  own.  He  confines  him- 
self to  the  circle  of  his  own  affairs  and  thrusts  not  his  fingers 
in  needless  fires.  .  .  He  sees  the  falseness  of  it  [the  world] 
and  therefore  learns  to  trust  himself  ever,  otheis  so  far  as 
not  to  be  damaged  by  their  disappointment  "  s"  There  must 
be  no  idle  leisure:  "those  that  are  prodigal  of  their  time  de- 
spise their  own  souls  "  M  Religion  must  be  active,  not  merely 
contemplative.  Contemplation  is,  indeed,  a  kind  of  self- 
indulgence  "To  neglect  this  fi.  e.,  bodily  employment  and 
mental  labor]  and  say,  T  will  pray  and  meditate,'  is  as  if 
your  servant  should  refuse  your  greatest  work,  and  tye  him- 
self to  some  lesser,  easie  part.  .  .  .  God  hath  commanded  you 
some  way  or  other  to  labour  for  your  daily  bread."  *2  The 
rich  are  no  more  excused  from  work  than  the  poor,  though 
they  may  rightly  use  their  riches  to  select  some  occupation 
specially  serviceable  to  others.  Covetousness  is  a  danger  to 
the  soul,  but  it  is  not  so  grave  a  danger  as  sloth.  "The  stand- 
ing pool  is  prone  to  putrefaction:  and  it  were  better  to  beat 


202  iHE   PURITAN    MOVEMENT 

down  the  body  and  to  keep  in  subjection  by  a  laborious  call- 
ing, than  through  luxury  to  become  a  cast-away  "  s]  So  far 
from  poverty  being  meritorious,  it  is  a  duty  to  choose  the 
more  profitable  occupation.  "If  God  show  you  a  way  in 
which  you  may  lawfully  get  more  than  in  another  way  (with- 
out wrong  to  your  soul  or  to  any  other),  if  you  refuse  this, 
and  choose  the  less  gainful  way,  you  cross  one  of  the  ends 
of  your  Calling,  and  you  refuse  to  be  God's  steward."  Lux- 
ury, unrestrained  pleasure,  personal  extravagance,  can  have 
no  place  in  a  Christian's  conduct,  for  " every  penny  which  is 
laid  out  .  .  .  must  be  done  as  by  God's  own  appointment." 
Even  excessive  devotion  to  friends  and  relations  is  to  be 
avoided.  "It  is  an  irrational  act,  and  therefore  not  fit  for  a 
rational  creature,  to  love  any  one  farther  than  reason  will 
allow  us.  ...  It  very  often  taketh  up  men's  minds  so  as  to 
hinder  their  love  to  God"84  The  Christian  life,  in  sho»t, 
must  be  systematic  and  organized,  the  work  of  an  iron  will 
and  a  cool  intelligence.  Those  who  have  read  Mill's  account 
of  his  father  must  have  been  struck  by  the  extent  to  which 
Utilitarianism  was  not  merely  a  political  doctrine,  but  a 
moral  attitude.  Some  of  the  links  in  the  Utilitarian  coat  of 
mail  were  forged,  it  may  be  suggested,  by  the  Puritan  di- 
vines of  the  seventeenth  century. 

The  practical  application  of  these  generalities  to  business 
is  set  out  in  the  numerous  works  composed  to  expound  the 
rules  of  Christian  conduct  in  the  varied  relations  of  life  If 
one  may  judge  by  their  titles — Navigation  Spintualizcd, 
Husbandry  Spiritualized,  The  Religious  Weaver^ — there 
must  have  been  a  considerable  demand  for  books  conducive 
to  professional  edification.  A  characteristic  specimen  is  The 
Tradesman's  Calling,^  by  Richard  Steele.  The  author,  after 
being  deprived  of  a  country  living  under  the  Act  of  Uniform- 
ity, spent  his  declining  years  as  a  minister  of  a  congregation 
at  Armourers  Hall  in  London,  and  may  be  presumed  to  have 
understood  the  spiritual  requirements  of  the  City  in  his  day, 
when  the  heroic  age  of  Puritanism  was  almost  over  and  en- 
thusiasm was  no  longer  a  virtue.  No  one  who  was  writing  a 
treatise  on  economic  ethics  today  would  address  himself  pri- 
marily to  the  independent  shopkeeper,  as  the  figure  most 
representative  of  the  business  community,  and  Steele's  book 
throws  a  flood  of  light  on  the  problems  and  outlook  of  the 
bourgeoisie,  in  an  age  before  the  center  of  economic  gravity 


TRIUMPH    OF   THE   ECONOMIC   VIRTUES  20J 

had  shifted  from  the  substantial  tradesman  to  the  exporting 
merchant,  the  industrial  capitalist  and  the  financier. 

Like  Baxter,  he  is  acquainted  with  the  teaching  of  earlier 
authorities  as  to  equity  in  bargaining.  He  is  doubtful,  how- 
ever, of  its  practical  utility.  Obvious  frauds  in  matters  of 
quality  and  weight  are  to  be  avoided;  an  honest  tradesman 
ought  not  to  corner  the  market,  or  "accumulate  two  or  three 
callings  merely  to  increase  his  riches,"  or  oppress  the  poor; 
nor  should  he  seek  more  than  "a  reasonable  proportion  of 
gain,"  or  "lie  on  the  catch  to  make  Lhis]  markets  of  others' 
straits."  But  Steele  rejects  as  useless  in  practice  the  various 
objective  standards  of  a  reasonable  profit — cost  of  produc- 
tion, standard  of  life,  customary  prices — which  had  been 
suggested  in  earlier  ages,  and  concludes  that  the  individual 
must  judge  for  himself  u'Here,  as  in  many  other  cases,  an 
upright  conscience  must  be  the  clerk  of  the  market." 

In  reality,  however,  the  characteristic  of  The  Tradesman's 
Calling,  as  of  the  age  in  which  it  was  written,  is  not  the 
relics  of  medieval  doctrine  which  linger  embalmed  in  its 
guileless  pages,  but  the  robust  common  sense,  which  carries 
the  author  lightly  over  traditional  scruples  on  a  tide  of  gen- 
ial, if  Philistine,  optimism.  For  his  main  thesis  is  a  com- 
fortable one — that  there  is  no  necessary  conflict  between  re- 
ligion and  business.  "Prudence  and  Piety  were  always  very 
good  friends.  .  .  .  You  may  gain  enough  of  both  worlds  if 
you  would  mind  each  in  its  place."  His  object  is  to  show 
how  that  agreeable  result  may  be  produced  by  dedicating 
business — with  due  reservations — to  the  service  of  God,  and 
he  has  naturally  little  to  say  on  the  moral  casuistry  of  eco- 
nomic conduct,  because  he  is  permeated  by  the  idea  that 
trade  itself  is  a  kind  of  religion.  A  tradesman's  first  duty  is  to 
get  a  full  insight  into  his  calling,  and  to  use  his  brains  to 
improve  it.  "He  that  hath  lent  you  talents  hath  also  said, 
'Occupy  till  I  come!'  Your  strength  is  a  talent,  your  parts 
are  talents,  and  so  is  your  time  How  is  it  that  ye  stand  all 
the  day  idle?  .  .  .  Your  trade  is  your  proper  province.  .  .  . 
Your  own  vineyard  you  should  keep.  .  .  .  Your  fancies,  your 
understandings,  your  memories  .  .  .  are  all  to  be  laid  out 
therein."  So  far  from  their  being  an  inevitable  collision  be- 
tween the  requirements  of  business  and  the  claims  of  reli- 
gion, they  walk  hand  in  hand.  By  a  fortunate  dispensation, 
the  virtues  enjoined  on  Christians — diligence,  moderation, 


204  THE   PURITAN    MOVEMENT 

sobriety,  thrift — are  the  very  qualities  most  conducive  to 
commercial  success  The  foundation  of  all  is  prudence,  and 
prudence  is  merely  another  name  for  the  "godly  wisdom 
[which]  comes  in  and  puts  due  bounds"  to  his  expenses, 
"and  teaches  the  tradesman  to  live  rather  somewhat  below 
than  at  all  above  his  income  "  Industry  comes  next,  and  in- 
dustry is  at  once  expedient  and  meritorious  It  will  keep  the 
tradesman  from  kt  frequent  and  needless  frequenting  of  tav- 
erns/' and  pin  him  to  his  shop,  "where  you  may  most  confi- 
dently expect  the  presence  and  blessing  of  God  " 

If  virtue  is  advantageous,  vice  is  ruinous.  Bad  company, 
speculation,  gambling,  politics,  and  "a  preposterous  zeal"  in 
religion — it  is  these  things  which  are  the  ruin  of  tradesmen 
Not,  indeed,  that  religion  is  to  be  neglected.  On  the  con- 
trary, it  "is  to  be  exercised  in  the  frequent  use  of  holy  ejac- 
ulations." What  is  deprecated  is  merely  the  unbusinesslike 
habit  of  "neglecting  a  man's  necessary  affairs  upon  pretence 
of  religious  worship."  But  these  faults,  common  and  uncom- 
mon alike,  are  precisely  those  to  be  avoided  by  the  sincere 
Christian,  who  must  not,  indeed,  deceive  or  oppress  his 
neighbor,  but  need  not  fly  to  the  other  extreme,  be  righteous 
overmuch,  or  refuse  to  "take  the  advantage  which  the  Prov- 
idence of  God  puts  into  his  hands  "  By  a  kind  of  happy, 
preestabhshed  harmony,  such  as  a  later  age  discovered  be- 
tween the  needs  of  society  and  the  self-interest  of  the  indi- 
vidual, success  in  business  is  in  itself  almost  a  sign  of  spir- 
itual grace,  for  it  is  proof  that  a  man  has  labored  faithfully 
in  his  vocation,  and  that  "God  has  blessed  his  trade  "  "Noth- 
ing will  pass  in  any  man's  account  except  it  be  done  in  the 
way  of  his  calling  .  .  Next  to  the  saving  his  soul,  |  the 
tradesman's!  care  and  business  is  to  serve  God  in  his  calling, 
and  to  drive  it  as  far  as  it  will  go  " 

When  duty  was  so  profitable,  might  not  profit-making  be 
a  duty?  Thus  argued  the  honest  pupils  of  Mr.  Gnpeman, 
the  schoolmaster  of  Love-gam,  a  market-town  in  the  county 
of  Coveting  in  the  north  8T  The  inference  was  illogical,  but 
how  attractive!  WThen  the  Rev  David  Jones  was  so  indis- 
creet as  to  preach  at  St  Mary  Woolnoth  in  Lombard  Street 
a  sermon  against  usury  on  the  text  "The  Pharisees  who 
were  covetous  heard  all  these  things  and  they  derided 
Christ,"  his  career  in  London  was  brought  to  an  abrupt 
conclusion.88 


TRIUMPH    OF    THE    ECONOMIC    VIRTUES  205 

The  springs  of  economic  conduct  He  in  regions  rarely  pene- 
trated by  moralists,  and  to  suggest  a  direct  reaction  of  theory 
on  practice  would  be  paradoxical.  But,  if  the  circumstances 
which  determine  that  certain  kinds  of  conduct  shall  be  profit- 
able are  economic,  those  which  decide  that  they  shall  be  the 
object  of  general  approval  are  primarily  moral  and  intel- 
lectual For  conventions  to  be  adopted  with  wholehearted 
enthusiasm,  to  be  not  merely  tolerated,  but  applauded,  to 
become  the  habit  of  a  nation  and  the  admiration  of  its  phi- 
losophers, the  second  condition  must  be  present  as  well  as 
the  first  The  insistence  among  men  of  pecuniary  motives, 
the  strength  of  economic  egotism,  the  appetite  for  gain — 
these  are  the  commonplaces  of  every  age  and  need  no  em- 
phasis What  is  significant  is  the  change  of  standards  which 
converted  a  natural  frailty  into  a  resounding  virtue  After 
all,  it  appears,  a  man  can  serve  two  masters,  for — so  hap- 
pily is  the  world  disposed — he  may  be  paid  by  one,  while 
he  works  for  the  other  Between  the  old-fashioned  denun- 
ciation of  uncharitable  covetousness  and  the  new-fashioned 
applause  of  economic  enterprise,  a  bridge  is  thrown  by  the 
argument  which  urges  that  enterprise  itself  is  the  discharge 
of  a  duty  imposed  by  God. 

In  the  year  16QO  appeared  a  pamphlet  entitled  A  Discourse 
of  Trade',  by  N  B  ,  M  D  80  Notable  for  its  enlightened  dis- 
cussion of  conventional  theories  of  the  balance  of  trade,  it 
is  a  good  specimen  of  an  indifferent  gcwu^  But  its  author- 
ship was  more  significant  than  its  argument  For  N.  B.  was 
Dr  Nicholas  Barbon;  and  Dr  Nicholas  Barbon,  currency 
expert,  pioneer  of  insurance,  and  enthusiast  for  land-banks, 
was  the  son  of  that  Praise-God  Barebones,  by  the  parody  of 
whose  alluring  surname  a  cynical  posterity  recorded  its  ver- 
dict on  the  brief  comedy  of  the  Rule  of  the  Saints  over 
Laodicean  Englishmen.  The  reaction  from  Puritan  rigor  to 
Restoration  license  is  the  most  familiar  of  platitudes.  The 
reaction  to  a  mundane  materialism  was  more  gradual,  more 
general,  and  ultimately  of  greater  significance  The  profli- 
gacy of  the  courtier  had  its  decorous  counterpart  in  the 
economic  orgies  of  the  tradesman  and  the  merchant.  Vo- 
taries, not  of  Bacchus,  but  of  a  more  exacting  and  more 
profitable  divinity,  they  celebrated  their  relief  at  the  dis- 
credit of  a  too  arduous  idealism,  by  plunging  with  redoubled 
zest  into  the  agreeable  fever  of  making  and  losing  money. 


206  THE    PURITAN    MOVEMENT 

The  transition  from  the  anabaptist  to  the  company  pro- 
moter was  less  abrupt  than  might  at  first  sight  be  supposed. 
It  had  been  prepared,  however  uninteiitior-'Jly,  by  Puritan 
moralists.  In  their  emphasis  on  the  moral  duty  of  untiring 
activity,  on  work  as  an  end  in  itself,  on  the  evils  of  luxury 
and  extravagance,  on  foresight  and  thrift,  on  moderation  and 
self-discipline  and  rational  calculation,  they  had  created  an 
ideal  of  Christian  conduct,  which  canonized  as  an  ethical 
principle  the  efficiency  which  economic  theorists  were  preach- 
ing as  a  specific  for  social  disorders.  It  was  as  captivating  as 
it  was  novel.  To  countless  generations  of  religious  thinkers, 
the  fundamental  maxim  of  Christian  social  ethics  had  seemed 
to  be  expressed  in  the  words  of  St.  Paul  to  Timothy:  " Hav- 
ing food  and  raiment,  let  us  be  therewith  content.  For  the 
love  of  money  is  the  root  of  all  evil."  Now,  while  as  always, 
the  world  battered  at  the  gate,  a  new  standard  was  raised 
within  the  citadel  by  its  own  defenders.  The  garrison  had 
discovered  that  the  invading  host  of  economic  appetites  wab, 
not  an  enemy,  but  an  ally.  Not  sufficiency  to  the  needs  of 
daily  life,  but  limitless  increase  and  expansion,  became  the 
goal  of  the  Christian's  efforts.  Not  consumption,  on  which 
the  eyes  of  earlier  sages  had  been  turned,  but  production, 
became  the  pivot  of  his  argument.  Not  an  easy-going  and 
open-handed  charity,  but  a  systematic  and  methodical  ac- 
cumulation, won  the  meed  of  praise  that  belongs  to  the  good 
and  faithful  servant.  The  shrewd,  calculating  commercial- 
ism which  tries  all  human  relations  by  pecuniary  standards, 
the  acquisitiveness  which  cannot  rest  while  there  are  com- 
petitors to  be  conquered  or  profits  to  be  won,  the  love  of 
social  power  and  hunger  for  economic  gain — these  irrepres- 
sible appetites  had  evoked  from  time  immemorial  the  warn- 
ings and  denunciations  of  saints  and  sages.  Plunged  in  the 
cleansing  waters  of  later  Puritanism,  the  qualities  which  less 
enlightened  ages  had  denounced  as  social  vices  emerged  as 
economic  virtues.  They  emerged  as  moral  virtues  as  well. 
For  the  world  exists  not  to  be  enjoyed,  but  to  be  conquered. 
Only  its  conqueror  deserves  the  name  of  Christian.  For  such 
a  philosophy,  the  question  "What  shall  it  pront  a  man?" 
carries  no  sting.  In  winning  the  world,  he  wins  the  salvation 
of  his  own  soul  as  well. 

The  idea  of  economic  progress  as  an  end  to  be  consciously 
sought,  while  ever  receding,  had  been  unfamiliar  to  most 


TRIUMPH    OF    THE    ECONOMIC    VIRTUES  207 

earlier  generations  of  Englishmen,  in  which  the  theme  of 
moralists  had  been  the  danger  of  unbridled  cupidity,  and 
the  main  aim  of  public  policy  had  been  the  stability  of  tra- 
tional  relationships.  It  found  a  new  sanction  in  the  identifi- 
cation of  labor  and  enterprise  with  the  service  of  God.  The 
magnificent  energy  which  changed  in  a  century  the  face  of 
material  civilization  was  to  draw  nourishment  from  that 
temper  The  worship  of  production  and  ever  greater  produc- 
tion— the  slavish  drudgery  of  the  millionaire  and  his  un- 
happy servants — was  to  be  hallowed  by  the  precepts  of  the 
same  compelling  creed 

Social  development  moves  with  a  logic  whose  inferences 
are  long  delayed,  and  the  day  of  these  remoter  applications 
had  not  yet  dawned  The  version  of  Christian  ethics  ex- 
pounded by  Puritanism  in  some  of  its  later  phases  was  still 
only  in  its  vigorous  youth  But  it  sailed  forward  on  a  flow- 
ing tide  It  had  an  unconscious  ally  in  the  pre-occupatkm 
with  economic  interests  which  found  expression  in  the  en- 
thusiasm of  business  politicians  for  a  commercial  Macht- 
pohtik  The  youthful  Commonwealth,  a  rival  of  Holland 
ufor  the  fairest  mistress  in  the  world — trade,"  MU  was  not  two 
years  old  when  it  made  its  own  essay  in  economic  imperial- 
ism "A  bare-faced  war"  for  commerce,  got  up  by  the  Royal 
African  Company  was  Clarendon's  verdict"1  on  the  Dutch 
war  of  1665-7  Five  years  later,  Shaftesbury  hounded  the 
City  against  Holland  with  the  cry  of  Dclcnda  est  Carthago. 
The  war  finance  of  the  Protectorate  had  made  it  necessary 
for  Cromwell  to  court  Dutch  and  Jewish,  as  well  as  native, 
capitalists,  and  the  impecunious  Government  of  the  Resto- 
ration was  in  the  hands  of  those  syndicates  of  goldsmiths 
whose  rapacity  the  Chancellor,  a  survivor  from  the  age  be- 
fore the  deluge,  when  aristocrats  still  despised  the  upstart 
plutocracy,  found  not  a  little  disgusting  <)2 

The  contemporary  progress  of  economic  thought  fortified 
no  less  the  mood  which  glorified  the  economic  virtues.  Eco- 
nomic science  developed  in  England,  not,  as  in  Germany,  as 
the  handmaid  of  public  administration,  nor,  as  in  France, 
through  the  speculations  of  philosophers  and  men  of  letters, 
but  as  the  interpreter  of  the  practical  interests  of  the  City. 
With  the  exception  of  Petty  and  Locke,  its  most  eminent 
practitioners  were  business  men,  and  the  questions  which 
excited  them  were  those,  neither  of  production  nor  of  social 


208  THE    PURITAN    MOVEMENT 

organization,  but  of  commerce  and  finance — the  balance  of 
trade,  tariffs,  interest,  currency  and  credit.  The  rise  of  Po- 
litical Arithmetic  after  the  Restoration,  profoundly  influ- 
enced, as  it  was,  by  the  Cartesian  philosophy  and  by  the 
progress  of  natural  science,  stamped  their  spontaneous  and 
doctrineless  individualism  with  the  seal  of  theoretical  or- 
thodoxy. Knowledge,  wrote  the  author  of  the  preface  to  a 
work  by  one  of  the  most  eminent  exponents  of  the  new  sci- 
ence, uin  great  measure  is  become  mechanical."  <J>  The  exact 
analysis  of  natural  conditions,  the  calculations  of  forces  and 
strains,  the  reduction  of  the  complex  to  the  operation  of  sim- 
ple, constant  and  measurable  forces,  was  the  natural  bias 
of  an  age  interested  primarily  in  mathematics  and  physics. 
Its  object  was  "to  express  itself  in  terms  of  number,  weight 
or  measure,  to  use  only  arguments  of  sense,  and  to  consider 
only  such  causes  as  have  visible  foundations  in  nature, 
leaving  those  that  depend  upon  the  mutable  minds,  opinions, 
appetites  and  passions  of  particular  men  to  the  considera- 
tion of  others  "  l(1 

In  such  an  atmosphere,  the  moral  casuistry,  which  had  oc- 
cupied so  large  a  place  in  the  earlier  treatment  of  social  and 
economic  subjects,  seemed  the  voice  of  an  antiquated  super- 
stition. Moreover,  the  main  economic  dogma  of  the  mercan- 
tilist had  an  affinity  with  the  main  ethical  dogma  of  the 
Puritan,  which  was  the  more  striking  because  the  coincidence 
was  undesigned.  To  the  former,  production,  not  consump- 
tion, was  the  pivot  of  the  economic  system,  and,  by  what 
seems  to  the  modern  reader  a  curious  perversion,  consump- 
tion is  applauded  only  because  it  offers  a  new  market  lor 
productive  energies.  To  the  latter,  the  cardinal  virtues  are 
precisely  those  which  find  in  the  strenuous  toils  of  industry 
and  commerce  their  most  natural  expression.  The  typical 
qualities  of  the  successful  business  life,  in  the  days  before 
the  rise  of  joint-stock  enterprise,  were  intensity  and  earnest- 
ness of  labor,  concentration,  system  and  method,  the  initia- 
tive which  broke  with  routine  and  the  foresight  which  post- 
poned the  present  to  the  future.  Advice  like  that  of  the  Rev- 
erend Mr.  Steele  to  his  City  congregation  was  admirably 
calculated  to  give  these  arduous  excellences  a  heightened 
status  and  justification.  The  lean  goddess,  Abstinence,  whom 
Mr.  Keynes,  in  a  passage  of  brilliant  indiscretion,  has  re- 
vealed as  the  tutelary  divinity  of  Victorian  England,  was  in- 


TRIUMPH    OF    THE    ECONOMIC    VIRTUES  209 

ducted  to  the  austere  splendors  of  her  ascetic  shrine  by  the 
pious  hands  of   Puritan  moralists. 

Such  teaching  fell  upon  willing  ears.  Excluded  by  legis- 
lation from  a  direct  participation  in  public  affairs,  Dissent- 
ers of  means  and  social  position  threw  themselves  into  the 
alternative  career  offered  by  commerce  and  finance,  and  did 
so  the  more  readily  because  religion  itself  had  blessed  their 
choice  If  they  conformed  the  character  given  them  by  their 
critics — "opinionating,  relying  much  upon  their  own  judg- 
ment .  .  ungrateful,  as  not  holding  themselves  beholden  to 
any  man  .  .  .  proud,  as  thinking  themselves  the  only  favor- 
ites of  God,  and  the  only  wise  or  virtuous  among  men'  'n — 
disposed  them  to  the  left  in  questions  of  Church  and  State. 
The  names  of  the  commercial  magnates  of  the  day  lend  some 
confirmation  to  the  suggestion  of  that  affinity  between  reli- 
gious radicalism  and  business  acumen  which  envious  con- 
temporaries expressed  in  their  sneers  at  the  "Presbyterian 
old  usurer/1 4ldevout  misers,'1  and  ^extorting  Ishban  "  '"'  The 
four  London  members  elected  in  1661  had  not  only  filled  the 
ordinary  civic  offices,  but  had  held  between  them  the  gov- 
ernorship of  the  East  India  Company,  the  deputy-governor- 
ship of  the  Levant  Company,  and  the  masterships  of  the 
Salters  and  Drapers  Companies,  two  of  them  were  said  to  be 
Presbyterians,  and  two  Independents  <l7  Of  the  committee  of 
leading  business  men  who  advised  Charles  II \s  Government 
on  questions  of  commercial  policy,  some,  like  Sir  Patience 
Ward  and  Michael  Godfrey,  represented  the  ultra-Prot- 
estantism of  the  Citv,  while  others,  like  Thomas  Papillon 
and  the  two  Houblons,  were  members  of  the  French  Hugue- 
not church  in  London  <KS  In  spite  of  the  bitter  commercial 
rivalry  with  Holland,  both  Dutch  capital  and  Dutch  ideas 
found  an  enthusiastic  welcome  in  London.""  Sir  George 
Downing  Charles  II 's  envoy  at  the  Hague,  who  endeavored 
to  acclimatize  Dutch  banking  methods  in  England,  and  who, 
according  to  Clarendon,  was  one  of  the  intriguers  who  pre- 
pared the  war  of  1665-7,  had  been  reared  in  the  Puritan 
severity  of  Salem  and  Harvard,  and  had  been  a  preacher  in 
the  regiment  of  Colonel  Okev  '  '  Pateison,  who  supplied  the 
idea  of  a  joint-stock  banking  corporation,  which  Michael 
Godfrey  popularized  in  the  City  and  Montagu  piloted 
through  Parliament,  was,  like  the  magnificent  Law,  a  Scotch 
company  promoter,  who  had  haunted  the  Hague  in  the  days 


210  1HE   PURITAN    MOVEMENT 

when  it  was  the  home  of  disconsolate  Whigs.102  Yarranton, 
most  ingenious  of  projectors,  had  been  an  officer  in  the  Par- 
liamentary army,  and  his  book  was  a  long  sermon  on  the 
virtues  of  the  Dutch. 1(-  Defoe,  who  wiote  the  idyll  of  tnc 
bourgeoisie  in  his  Complete  English  Tradesman,  was  born  oi 
nonconformist  parents,  and  was  intended  for  the  ministry  be- 
fore, having  failed  in  trade,  he  took  up  politics  and  litera- 
ture.1'^ In  his  admirable  study  of  the  iron  industry,  Mr. 
Ashton  has  shown  that  the  most  eminent  iron-masters  of  the 
eighteenth  century  belonged  as  a  rule  to  the  Puritan  connec- 
tion.304 They  had  their  prototype  in  the  seventeenth  century 
in  Baxter's  friend,  Thomas  Foley,  "who  from  almost  nothing 
did  get  about  £57000  per  annum  or  more  by  iron  works  ''  "" 
To  such  a  generation,  a  creed  which  transformed  the  ac- 
quisition of  wealth  from  a  drudgery  or  a  temptation  into  a 
moral  duty  was  the  milk  of  lions.  It  was  not  that  religion 
was  expelled  from  practical  life,  but  that  religion  itself  gave 
it  a  foundation  of  granite.  In  that  keen  atmosphere  of  eco- 
nomic enterprise,  the  ethics  of  the  Puritan  bore  some  resem- 
blance to  those  associated  later  with  the  name  of  Smiles  The 
good  Christian  was  not  wholly  dissimilar  from  the  economic 
man. 

IV     THE  NEW  MEDICINE  FOR  POVERTY 

To  applaud  certain  qualities  is  by  implication  to  condemn 
the  habits  and  institutions  which  appear  to  conflict  with 
them.  The  recognition  accorded  by  Puritan  ethics  to  the 
economic  virtues,  in  an  age  when  such  virtues  were  rarer 
than  they  are  today,  gave  a  timely  stimulus  to  economic 
efficiency.  But  it  naturally,  if  unintentionally,  modified  the 
traditional  attitude  towards  social  obligations.  For  the  spon- 
taneous, doctrineless  individualism,  which  became  the  rule 
of  English  public  life  a  century  before  the  philosophy  of  it 
was  propounded  by  Adam  Smith,  no  single  cause  was  re- 
sponsible. But,  simultaneously  with  the  obvious  movements 
in  the  world  of  affairs — the  discrediting  of  the  ideal  of  a 
paternal,  authoritarian  Government,  the  breakdown  of  cen- 
tral control  over  local  administration,  the  dislocation  caused 
by  the  Civil  War,  the  expansion  of  trade  and  the  shifting 
of  industry  from  its  accustomed  seats — it  is  perhaps  not 
fanciful  to  detect  in  the  ethics  of  Puritanism  one  force  con- 


THE   NEW    MEDICINE    FOR    POVERTY  211 

Lributing  to  the  change  in  social  policy  which  is  noticeable  , 
after  the  middle  of  the  century. 

The  loftiest  teaching  cannot  escape  from  its  own  shadow. 
To  urge  that  the  Christian  life  must  be  lived  in  a  zealous 
discharge  of  private  duties — how  necessary!  Yet  how  readily 
perverted  to  the  suggestion  that  there  are  no  vital  social  ob- 
ligations beyond  and  above  them'  To  insist  that  the  indi- 
vidual is  responsible,  that  no  man  can  save  his  brother,  that 
the  essence  of  religion  is  the  contact  of  the  soul  with  its 
Maker,  how  true  and  indispensable!  But  how  easy  to  slip 
from  that  truth  into  the  suggestion  that  society  is  without 
responsibility,  that  no  man  can  help  his  brother,  that  the  so- 
cial order  and  its  consequences  are  not  even  the  scaffolding 
by  which  men  may  climb  to  greater  heights,  but  something 
external,  alien  and  irrelevant — something,  at  best,  indiffer- 
ent to  the  life  of  the  spirit,  and,  at  worst,  the  sphere  of  the 
letter  which  killeth  and  of  the  reliance  on  works  which  en- 
snares the  soul  into  the  slumber  of  death!  In  emphasizing 
that  God's  Kingdom  is  not  of  this  world,  Puritanism  did  not 
always  escape  the  suggestion  that  this  world  is  no  part  of 
God's  Kingdom.  The  complacent  victim  of  that  false  antith- 
esis between  the  social  mechanism  and  the  life  of  the  spirit, 
which  was  to  tyrannize  over  English  religious  thought  for 
the  next  two  centuries,  it  enthroned  religion  in  the  privacy 
of  the  individual  soul,  not  without  some  sighs  of  sober  satis- 
faction at  its  abdication  from  society.  Professor  Dicey  has 
commented  on  the  manner  in  which  uthe  appeal  of  the  Evan- 
gelicals to  personal  religion  corresponds  with  the  appeal  of 
Benthamite  Liberals  to  individual  energy  "  HU>  The  same  af- 
finity between  religious  and  social  interests  found  an  even 
clearer  expression  in  the  Puritan  movement  of  the  seven- 
teenth century.  Individualism  in  religion  led  insensibly,  if 
not  quite  logically,  to  an  individualist  morality,  and  an  in- 
dividualist morality  to  a  disparagement  of  the  significance 
of  the  social  fabric  as  compared  with  personal  character. 

A  practical  example  of  that  change  of  emphasis  is  given  by 
the  treatment  accorded  to  the  questions  of  Enclosure  and  of 
Pauperism.  For  a  century  and  a  half  the  progress  of  enclos- 
ing had  been  a  burning  issue,  flaring  up,  from  time  to  time, 
into  acute  agitation.  During  the  greater  part  of  that  period, 
from  Latimer  in  the  thirties  of  the  sixteenth  century  to  Laud 
in  the  thirties  of  the  seventeenth,  the  attitude  of  religious 


212  THE   PURITAN    MOVEMENT 

teachers  had  been  one  of  condemnation.  Sermon  after  ser- 
mon and  pamphlet  after  pamphlet — not  to  mention  Statutes 
and  Royal  Commissions — had  been  launched  against  depop- 
ulation. The  appeal  had  been,  not  merely  to  public  policy, 
but  to  religion.  Peasant  and  lord,  in  their  different  degrees, 
are  members  of  one  Christian  commonwealth,  within  which 
the  law  of  charity  must  bridle  the  corroding  appetite  for 
economic  gain.  In  such  a  mystical  corporation,  knit  together 
by  mutual  obligations,  no  man  may  press  his  advantage 
to  the  full,  for  no  man  may  seek  to  live  " outside  the  body 
of  the  Church." 

.Sabotaged  by  the  unpaid  magistracy  of  country  gentle- 
men, who  had  been  the  obstructive  agents  of  local  adminis- 
tration, the  practical  application  of  such  doctrines  had  al- 
ways been  intermittent,  and,  when  the  Long  Parliament 
struck  the  weapon  of  administrative  law  from  the  hands  of 
the  Crown,  it  had  ceased  altogether.  But  the  politics  of  West- 
minster were  not  those  of  village  and  borough  The  events 
which  seemed  to  aristocratic  Parliamentarians  to  close  the 
revolution  seemed  to  the  left  wing  of  the  victorious  army 
only  to  begin  it  In  that  earliest  and  most  turbulent  of  Eng- 
lish democracies,  where  buff -coat  taught  scripture  politics  to 
his  general,  the  talk  was  not  merely  of  political,  but  of  social, 
reconstruction  The  program  of  the  Levellers,  who  more 
than  any  other  party  could  claim  to  express  the  aspirations 
of  the  unprivileged  classes,  included  a  demand,  not  only  for 
annual  or  biennial  Parliaments,  manhood  suffrage,  a  redistri- 
bution of  seats  in  proportion  to  population,  and  the  abolition 
of  the  veto  of  the  House  of  Lords,  but  also  that  "you  would 
have  laid  open  all  enclosures  of  fens  and  other  commons,  or 
have  them  enclosed  only  or  chiefly  for  the  benefit  of  the 
poor  "  1(/T  Theoretical  communism,  repudiated  b>  the  leading 
Levellers,  found  its  expression  in  the  agitation  of  the  Dig- 
gers, on  whose  behalf  Winstanley  argued  that,  "seeing  the 
common  people  of  England,  by  joynt  consent  of  person  and 
purse,  have  caste  out  Charles,  our  Norman  oppressour 
the  land  now  is  to  returne  into  the  joynt  hands  of  those  who 
have  conquered,  that  is  the  commonours,"  and  that  the  vic- 
tory over  the  King  was  incomplete,  as  long  as  "wee  .  .  .  re- 
mayne  slaves  still  to  the  kingly  power  in  the  hands  of  lords 
of  manors."108 

Nor  was  it  only  from  the  visionary  and  the  zealot  that  the 


THE   NEW   MEDICINE    FOR   POVERTY  2 IS 

pressure  for  redress  proceeded.  When  the  shattering  of  tra- 
ditional authority  seemed  for  a  moment  to  make  all  things 
new,  local  grievances,  buried  beneath  centuries  of  dull  op* 
pression,  started  to  life,  and  in  several  Midland  counties  the 
peasants  rose  to  pull  down  the  hated  hedges  At  Leicester, 
where  in  1 649  there  were  rumors  of  a  popular  movement  to 
throw  down  the  enclosures  of  the  neighboring  forest,  the 
City  Council  took  the  matter  up.  A  petition  was  drafted, 
setting  out  the  economic  and  social  evils  attending  enclosure, 
and  proposing  the  establishment  of  machinery  to  check  it, 
consisting  of  a  committee  without  whose  assent  enclosing 
was  not  to  be  permitted.  A  local  minister  was  instructed  to 
submit  the  petition  to  Parliament,  "which  hath  still  a  watch- 
ful eye  and  open  ear  to  redress  the  common  grievances  of 
the  nation."  309  The  agent  selected  to  present  the  city's  case 
was  the  Rev.  John  Moore,  a  prolific  pamphleteer,  who  for 
several  years  attacked  the  depopulating  landlord  with  all 
the  fervor  of  Latimer,  though  with  even  less  than  Latimer's 
success 

Half  a  century  before,  such  commotions  would  have  been 
followed  by  the  passing  of  Depopulation  Acts  and  the  issue 
of  a  Royal  Commission.  But,  in  the  ten  years  since  the  meet- 
ing of  the  Long  Parliament,  the  whole  attitude  of  public 
policy  towards  the  movement  had  begun  to  change.  Con- 
fiscations, compositions  and  war  taxation  had  effected  a  rev- 
olution in  the  distribution  of  property,  similar,  on  a  smaller 
scale,  to  that  which  had  taken  place  at  the  Reformation.  As 
land  changed  hands,  customary  relations  were  shaken  and 
new  interests  were  created.  Enclosure,  as  Moore  com- 
plained,11" was  being  pushed  forward  by  means  of  law  suits 
ending  in  Chancery  decrees.  It  was  not  to  be  expected  that 
City  merchants  and  members  of  the  Committee  for  Com- 
pounding, some  of  whom  had  found  land  speculation  a  prof- 
itable business,  should  hear  with  enthusiasm  a  proposal  to 
revive  the  old  policy  of  arresting  enclosures  by  State  inter- 
ference, at  which  the  gentry  had  grumbled  for  more  than 
a  century. 

In  these  circumstances,  it  is  not  surprising  that  reformers 
should  have  found  the  open  ear  of  Parliament  impenetrably 
closed  to  agrarian  grievances.  Nor  was  it  only  the  political 
and  economic  environment  which  had  changed.  The  revolu- 
tion in  thought  was  equally  profound.  The  theoretical  basis 


214  THE   PURITAN    MOVEMENT 

of  the  policy  of  protecting  the  peasant  by  preventing  en- 
closure had  been  a  conception  of  landownership  which  re- 
garded its  rights  and  its  duties  as  inextricably  interwoven. 
Property  was  not  merely  a  source  of  income,  but  a  public 
function,  and  its  use  was  limited  by  social  obligations  and 
necessities  of  State.  With  such  a  doctrine  the  classes  who  had 
taken  the  lead  in  the  struggle  against  the  monarchy  could 
make  no  truce.  Its  last  vestiges  finally  disappeared  when 
the  Restoration  Parliament  swept  away  military  tenures,  and 
imposed  on  the  nation,  in  the  shape  of  an  excise,  the  finan- 
cial burden  previously  borne  by  themselves. 

The  theory  which  took  its  place,  and  which  was  to  become 
in  the  eighteenth  century  almost  a  religion,  was  that  ex- 
pressed by  Locke,  when  he  described  property  as  a  right  an- 
terior to  the  existence  of  the  State,  and  argued  that  uthe 
supreme  power  cannot  take  from  any  man  any  part  of  his 
property  without  his  own  consent  "  But  Locke  merely  poured 
into  a  philosophical  mould  ideas  which  had  been  hammered 
out  in  the  stress  of  political  struggles,  and  which  were  al- 
ready the  commonplace  of  landowner  and  merchant  The 
view  of  society  held  by  that  part  of  the  Puritan  movement 
which  was  socially  and  politically  influential  had  been  ex- 
pressed by  Ireton  and  Cromwell  in  their  retort  to  the  demo- 
crats in  the  army.  It  was  that  only  the  freeholders  constitut- 
ed the  body  politic,  and  that  they  could  use  their  property 
as  they  pleased,  uncontrolled  by  obligations  to  any  superior, 
or  by  the  need  of  consulting  the  mass  of  men,  who  were  mere 
tenants  at  will,  with  no  fixed  interest  or  share  in  the  land  of 
the  kingdom  nl  Naturally,  this  change  of  ideas  had  profound 
reactions  on  agrarian  policy.  Formerly  a  course  commending 
itself  to  all  public-spirited  persons,  the  prevention  of  en- 
closure was  now  discredited  as  the  program  of  a  sect  of  re- 
ligious and  political  radicals.  When  Major-General  Whalley 
in  1656  introduced  a  measure  to  regulate  and  restrict  the 
enclosure  of  commons,  framed,  apparently,  on  the  lines  pro- 
posed by  the  authorities  of  Leicester,  there  was  an  instant 
outcry  from  members  that  it  would  "destroy  property,"  and 
the  bill  was  refused  a  second  reading  11J  Alter  hie  Restora- 
tion the  tide  began  to  run  more  strongly  in  the  same  direc- 
tion. Enclosure  had  already  become  the  hobby  of  the  coun- 
try gentleman.  Experts  advocated  it  on  economic  grounds, 
and  legislation  to  facilitate  it  was  introduced  into  Parlia- 


THE   NEW   MEDICINE   FOR   POVERTY  21$ 

merit.  Though  its  technique  still  remained  to  be  elaborated, 
the  attitude  which  was  to  be  decisive  in  the  eighteenth  cen- 
tury had  already  been  crystallized. 

The  change  of  policy  was  striking.  The  reason  of  it  was 
not  merely  that  political  conditions  made  the  landed  gentry 
omnipotent,  and  that  the  Royalist  squirearchy,  who  streamed 
back  to  their  plundered  manors  in  1660,  were  in  no  mood  to 
countenance  a  revival,  by  the  Government  of  Charles  II,  of 
the  administrative  interference  with  the  rights  of  property 
which  had  infuriated  them  in  the  Government  of  Charles  I. 
It  was  that  opinion  as  to  social  policy  had  changed,  and 
changed  not  least  among  men  of  religion  themselves.  The 
pursuit  of  economic  self-interest,  which  is  the  law  of  nature, 
is  already  coming  to  be  identified  by  the  pious  with  the  op- 
eration of  the  providential  plan,  which  is  the  law  of  God. 
Enclosures  will  increase  the  output  of  wool  and  grain.  Each 
man  knows  best  what  his  land  is  suited  to  produce,  and  the 
general  interest  will  be  best  served  by  leaving  him  free  to 
produce  it.  "It  is  an  undeniable  maxim  that  every  one  by  the 
light  of  nature  and  reason  will  do  that  which  makes  for  his 
greatest  advantage.  .  .  .  The  advancement  of  private  persons 
will  be  the  advantage  of  the  public 

It  is  significant  that  such  considerations  were  adduced, 
not  by  an  economist,  but  by  a  minister.  For  the  argument 
wdb  ethical  as  well  as  economic,  and,  when  Moore  appealed 
to  the  precepts  of  traditional  morality  to  bridle  pecuniary 
interests,  he  provoked  the  retort  that  a  judicious  attention 
to  pecuniary  interests  was  an  essential  part  of  an  enlightened 
morality.  What  the  poor  need  for  their  spiritual  health  is — 
to  use  the  favorite  catchword  of  the  age — "regulation,"  and 
regulation  is  possible  only  if  they  work  under  the  eye  of  an 
employer.  In  the  eyes  of  the  austere  moralists  of  the  Resto- 
ration, the  first,  and  most  neglected,  virtue  of  the  poor  is 
industry.  Common  rights  encourage  idleness  by  offering  a 
precarious  and  demoralizing  livelihood  to  men  who  ought 
to  be  at  work  for  a  master.  It  is  not  surprising,  therefore, 
that  the  admonitions  of  religious  teachers  against  the  wick- 
edness of  joining  house  to  house  and  field  to  field  should 
almost  entirely  cease.  Long  the  typical  example  of  unchar- 
itable covetousness,  enclosure  is  now  considered,  not  merely 
economically  expedient,  but  morally  beneficial.  Baxter,  with 
all  his  scrupulousness — partly,  perhaps,  because  of  his  scru- 


216  THE   PURITAN    MOVEMENT 

pulousness — differs  from  most  earlier  divines  in  giving  a 
qualified  approval  to  enclosure  "done  in  moderation  by  a 
pious  man/'  for  the  characteristic  reason  that  a  master  can 
establish  a  moral  discipline  among  his  employees,  which 
they  would  miss  if  they  worked  for  themselves.  What  mat- 
ters, in  short,  is  not  their  circumstances,  but  their  charac- 
ter. If  they  lose  as  peasants,  they  will  gain  as  Christians. 
Opportunities  for  spiritual  edification  are  more  important 
than  the  mere  material  environment.  If  only  the  material 
environment  were  not  itself  among  the  forces  determining 
men's  capacity  to  be  edified! 

The  temper  which  deplored  that  the  open-field  village  was 
not  a  school  of  the  severer  virtues  turned  on  pauperism  and 
poor  relief  an  even  more  shattering  criticism  There  is  no 
province  of  social  life  in  which  the  fashioning  of  a  new  scale 
of  ethical  values  on  the  Puritan  anvil  is  more  clearly  re- 
vealed. In  the  little  communities  of  peasants  and  crafts- 
men which  composed  medieval  England,  all,  when  Heaven 
sent  a  bad  harvest,  had  starved  together,  and  the  misery  of 
the  sick,  the  orphan  and  the  aged  had  appeared  as  a  per- 
sonal calamity,  not  as  a  social  problem.  Apart  from  a  few 
precocious  theorists,  who  hinted  at  the  need  for  a  universal 
and  secular  system  of  provision  for  distress,  the  teaching 
most  characteristic  of  medieval  writers  had  been  that  the 
relief  of  the  needy  was  a  primary  obligation  on  those  who 
had  means.  St.  Thomas,  who  in  this  matter  is  typical,  quotes 
with  approval  the  strong  words  of  St  Ambrose  about  those 
who  cling  to  the  bread  of  the  starving,  insists  on  the  idea 
that  property  is  stewardship,  and  concludes  —a  conclusion 
not  always  drawn  from  that  well-worn  phrase — that  to  with- 
hold alms  when  there  is  evident  and  urgent  necessity  is 
mortal  sin111  Popular  feeling  had  lent  a  half-mystical 
glamour  both  to  poverty  and  to  the  compassion  by  which 
poverty  was  relieved,  for  poor  men  were  God's  friends.  At 
best,  the  poor  were  thought  to  represent  our  Lord  in  a  pe- 
culiarly intimate  way — ain  that  sect,"  as  Langland  said, 
"our  Saviour  saved  all  mankind" — and  it  was  necessary  for 
the  author  of  a  religious  manual  to  explain  that  the  rich,  as 
such,  were  not  necessarily  hateful  to  God  n  '  At  worst,  men 
reflected  that  the  prayers  of  the  poor  availed  much,  and 
that  the  sinner  had  been  saved  from  hell  by  throwing  a  loaf 
of  bread  to  a  beggar,  even  though  a  curse  went  with  it.  The 


THE   NEW    MEDICINE   FOR    POVERTY  217 

alms  bestowed  today  would  be  repaid  a  thousandfold,  when 
the  soul  took  its  dreadful  journey  amid  rending  briars  and 
scorching  flames. 

If  ever  thou  gavest  hosen  and  shoon, 

Evcne  mghte  and  alle, 
Sit  thee  down  and  put  them  on, 

And  Chnste  receive  thy  saule. 

If  hosen  and  shoon  thou  gavest  nane, 

Evene  mghte  and  alle, 
The  whinnes  shall  pncke  thee  to  the  bare  bane, 

And  Chnstc  receive  thy  saule. 


If  ever  thou  gavest  meate  or  dnnke, 

Evene  mghte  and  alle, 
The  fire  shall  never  make  thee  shrmke, 

And  Chn\te  receive  thy  saule. 

If  meate  or  dnnke  thou  gavest  nanc, 

Evene  mghte  and  alle, 
The  fire  will  burne  thee  to  the  bare  bane, 

And  Chn\te  receive  thy  saule 

This  ae  niphte,  this  ae  mghte, 

Evene  mghte  and  alle, 
Fire,  and  sleete,  and  candle-hghte, 

And  Chn^te  receive  thy  saule  ll{> 

The  social  character  of  wealth,  which  had  been  the  essence 
of  the  medieval  doctrine,  was  asserted  by  English  divines  in 
the  sixteenth  century  with  redoubled  emphasis,  precisely 
because  the  growing  individualism  of  the  age  menaced  the 
traditional  conception.  "The  poor  man,"  preached  Latimer, 
"hath  title  to  the  rich  man's  goods;  so  that  the  rich  man 
ought  to  let  the  poor  man  have  part  of  his  riches  to  help  and 
to  comfort  him  withal  "  11T  Nor  had  that  sovereign  indiffer- 
ence to  the  rigors  of  the  economic  calculus  disappeared, 
when,  under  the  influence  partly  of  humanitarian  represen- 
tatives of  the  Renaissance  like  Vives,  partly  of  religious 
reformers,  partly  of  their  own  ambition  to  gather  all  the 
threads  of  social  administration  into  their  own  hands,  the 
statesmen  of  the  sixteenth  century  set  themselves  to  organ- 
ize a  secular  system  of  poor  relief.  In  England,  after  three 
generations  in  which  the  attempt  was  made  to  stamp  out 
vagrancy  by  police  measures  of  hideous  brutality,  the  mo- 


218  THE   PURITAN   MOVEMENT 

mentous  admission  was  made  that  its  cause  was  economic 
distress,  not  merely  personal  idleness,  and  that  the  whip  had 
no  terrors  for  the  man  who  must  either  tramp  or  starve. 
The  result  was  the  celebrated  Acts  imposing  a  compulsory 
poor-rate  and  requiring  the  able-bodied  man  to  be  set  on 
work.  The  Privy  Council,  alert  to  prevent  disorder,  drove 
lethargic  justices  hard,  and  down  to  the  Civil  War  the  sys- 
tem was  administered  with  fair  regularity.  But  the  Eliza- 
bethan Poor  Law  was  never  designed  to  be  what,  with  dis- 
astrous results,  it  became  in  the  eighteenth  and  early  nine- 
teenth centuries,  the  sole  measure  for  coping  with  economic 
distress.  While  it  provided  relief,  it  was  but  the  last  link  in 
a  chain  of  measures — the  prevention  of  evictions,  the  control 
of  food  supplies  and  prices,  the  attempt  to  stabilize  employ- 
ment and  to  check  unnecessary  dismissals  of  workmen — 
intended  to  mitigate  the  forces  which  made  relief  necessary 
Apart  from  the  Poor  Law,  the  first  forty  years  of  the  sev- 
enteenth century  were  prolific  in  the  private  chantv  which 
founded  alms-houses  and  hospitals,  and  established  funds  to 
provide  employment  or  to  aid  struggling  tradesmen.  The 
appeal  was  still  to  religion,  which  owed  to  poverty  a  kind 
of  reverence. 

It  was  Thy  choice,  whilst  Thou  on  earth  didst  stay, 
And  hadst  not  whereupon  Thy  head  to  lay  11K 

"What,  speak  you  of  such  things?"  said  Nicholas  Ferrar 
on  his  death-bed  to  one  who  commended  his  charities.  "It 
would  have  been  but  a  suitable  return  for  me  to  have  given 
all  I  had,  and  not  to  have  scattered  a  few  crumbs  of  alms 
here  and  there/'11'' 

It  was  inevitable  that,  in  the  anarchy  of  the  Civil  War, 
both  private  charity  and  public  relief  should  fall  on  evil 
days.  In  London,  charitable  endowments  seem  to  have  suf- 
fered from  more  than  ordinary  malversation,  and  there  were 
complaints  that  the  income  both  of  Bridewell  and  of  the 
Hospitals  was  seriously  reduced.120  In  the  country,  the  rec- 
ords of  Quarter  Sessions  paint  a  picture  of  confusion,  in 
which  the  machinery  of  presentment  by  constables  to  jus- 
tice has  broken  down,  and  a  long  wail  arises,  that  thieves 
are  multiplied,  the  poor  are  neglected,  and  vagrants  wander 
to  and  fro  at  their  will.121  The  administrative  collapse  of  the 


THE    NEW    MEDICINE   FOR   POVERTY  219 

Elizabethan  Poor  Law  continued  after  the  Restoration,  and 
twenty-three  years  later  Sir  Matthew  Hale  complained  that 
the  sections  in  it  relating  to  the  provision  of  employment 
were  a  dead  letter.122  Always  unpopular  with  the  local  au- 
thorities, whom  they  involved  in  considerable  trouble  and 
expense,  it  is  not  surprising  that,  with  the  cessation  of  pres- 
sure by  the  Central  Government,  they  should,  except  here 
and  there,  have  been  neglectd.  What  is  more  significant, 
however,  than  the  practical  deficiencies  in  the  administra- 
tion of  relief,  was  the  rise  of  a  new  school  of  opinion,  which 
regarded  with  repugnance  the  whole  body  of  social  theory 
of  which  both  private  charity  and  public  relief  had  been  the 
expression. 

"The  generall  rule  of  all  England,"  wrote  a  pamphleteer 
in  1646,  uis  to  whip  and  punish  the  wandring  beggars  .  .  . 
and  so  many  justices  execute  one  branch  of  that  good  Stat- 
ute (which  is  the  point  of  justice),  but  as  for  the  point  of 
charitie,  they  leave  \\t]  undone,  which  is  to  provide  houses 
and  convenient  places  to  set  the  poore  to  work."  123  The 
House  of  Commons  appears  to  have  been  conscious  that  the 
complaint  had  some  foundation;  in  1649  it  ordered  that  the 
county  justices  should  be  required  to  see  that  stocks  of  ma- 
terial were  provided  as  the  law  required,124  and  the  question 
of  preparing  new  legislation  to  ensure  that  persons  in  dis- 
tress should  be  found  employment  was  on  several  occasions 
referred  to  committees  of  the  House.125  Nothing  seems, 
however,  to  have  come  of  these  proposals,  nor  was  the 
Elizabethan  policy  of  "setting  the  poor  on  work"  that  which 
was  most  congenial  to  the  temper  of  the  time.  Upon  the 
admission  that  distress  was  the  result,  not  of  personal  defi- 
ciencies, but  of  economic  causes,  with  its  corollary  that  its 
victims  had  a  legal  right  to  be  maintained  by  society,  the 
growing  individualism  of  the  age  turned  the  same  frigid 
scepticism  as  was  later  directed  against  the  Speenhamland 
policy  by  the  reformers  of  1834.  Like  the  friends  of  Job,  it 
saw  in  misfortune,  not  the  chastisement  of  love,  but  the 
punishment  for  sin.  The  result  was  that,  while  the  penalties 
on  the  vagrant  were  redoubled,  religious  opinion  laid  less 
emphasis  on  the  obligation  of  charity  than  upon  the  duty 
of  work,  and  that  the  admonitions  which  had  formerly  been 
turned  upon  uncharitable  covetousness  were  now  directed 
against  improvidence  and  idleness.  The  characteristic  senti- 


220  THE  PURITAN   MOVEMENT 

ment  was  that  of  Milton's  friend,  Hartlib:  "The  law  of  God 
saith,  'he  that  will  not  work,  let  him  not  eat.'  This  would 
be  a  sore  scourge  and  smart  whip  for  idle  persons  if  ... 
none  should  be  suffered  to  eat  till  they  had  wrought  for 

j£  »  126 

The  new  attitude  found  expression  in  the  rare  bursts  of 
public  activity  provoked  by  the  growth  of  pauperism  be- 
tween 1640  and  1660.  The  idea  of  dealing  with  it  on  sound 
business  principles,  by  means  of  a  corporation  which  would 
combine  profit  with  philanthropy,  was  being  sedulously 
preached  by  a  small  group  of  reformers.127  Parliament  took 
it  up,  and  in  1649  passed  an  Act  for  the  relief  and  employ- 
ment of  the  poor  and  the  punishment  of  beggars,  under 
which  a  company  was  to  be  established  with  power  to  ap- 
prehend vagrants,  to  offer  them  the  choice  between  work  and 
whipping,  and  to  set  to  compulsory  labor  all  other  poor  per- 
sons, including  children  without  means  of  maintenance.128 
Eight  years  later  the  prevalence  of  vagrancy  produced  an 
Act  of  such  extreme  severity  as  almost  to  recall  the  sugges- 
tion made  a  generation  later  by  Fletcher  of  Saltoun,  that 
vagrants  should  be  sent  to  the  galleys.  It  provided  that,  since 
offenders  could  rarely  be  taken  in  the  act,  any  vagrant  who 
failed  to  satisfy  the  justices  that  he  had  a  good  reason  for 
being  on  the  roads  should  be  arrested  and  punished  as  a 
sturdy  beggar,  whether  actually  begging  or  not.129 

The  protest  against  indiscriminate  almsgiving,  as  the 
parade  of  a  spurious  religion,  which  sacrified  character  to  a 
formal  piety,  was  older  than  the  Reformation,  but  it  had 
been  given  a  new  emphasis  by  the  reformers.  Luther  had 
denounced  the  demands  of  beggars  as  blackmail,  and  the 
Swiss  reformers  had  stamped  out  the  remnants  of  monastic 
charity,  as  a  bribe  ministered  by  Popery  to  dissoluteness 
and  demoralization.  "I  conclude  that  all  the  large  givings  of 
the  papists,"  preached  an  English  divine  in  the  reign  of 
Elizabeth,  "of  which  at  this  day  many  make  so  great  brags, 
because  they  be  not  done  in  a  reverent  regard  of  the  com- 
mandment of  the  Lord,  in  love,  and  of  an  inward  being 
touched  with  the  calamities  of  the  needy,  but  for  to  be  well 
reported  of  before  men  whilst  they  are  alive,  and  to  be 
prayed  for  after  they  are  dead  ...  are  indeed  no  alms,  but 
Pharisaical  trumpets."  1:>J°  The  rise  of  a  commercial  civiliza- 
tion, the  reaction  against  the  authoritarian  social  policy  of 


THE    NEW    MEDICINE    FOR    POVERTY  221 

the  Tudors,  and  the  progress  of  Puritanism  among  the  mid- 
dle classes,  all  combined  in  the  next  half-century  to  sharpen 
the  edge  of  that  doctrine.  Nurtured  in  a  tradition  which 
made  the  discipline  of  character  by  industry  and  self-denial 
the  center  of  its  ethical  scheme,  the  Puritan  moralist  was 
undisturbed  by  any  doubts  as  to  whether  even  the  seed  of 
the  righteous  might  not  sometimes  be  constrained  to  beg  its 
bread,  and  met  the  taunt  that  the  reputation  of  good  works 
was  the  cloak  for  a  conscienceless  egoism  with  the  retort 
that  the  easy-going  open-handedness  of  the  sentimentalist 
was  not  less  selfish  in  its  motives  and  was  more  corrupting 
to  its  objects  liAs  for  idle  beggars,"  wrote  Steele,  "happy 
for  them  if  fewer  people  spent  their  foolish  pity  upon  their 
bodies,  and  if  more  shewed  some  wise  compassion  upon  their 
souls  "  1  n  That  the  greatest  of  evils  is  idleness,  that  the 
poor  are  the  victims,  not  of  circumstances,  but  of  their  own 
"idle,  irregular  and  wicked  courses,11  that  the  truest  charity 
is  not  to  enervate  them  by  relief,  but  so  to  reform  their 
characters  that  relief  may  be  unnecessary — such  doctrines 
turned  severity  from  a  sin  into  a  duty,  and  froze  the  im- 
pulse of  natural  pity  with  the  assurance  that,  if  indulged, 
it  would  perpetuate  the  suffering  which  it  sought  to  allay. 

Few  tricks  of  the  unsophisticated  intellect  are  more  curi- 
ous that  the  naive  psychology  of  the  business  man,  who 
ascribes  his  achievements  to  his  own  unaided  efforts,  in 
bland  unconsciousness  of  a  social  order  without  whose  con- 
tinuous support  and  vigilant  protection  he  would  be  as  a 
lamb  bleating  in  the  desert  That  individualist  complex  owes 
part  of  its  self-assurance  to  the  suggestion  of  Puritan  mor- 
alists, that  practical  success  is  at  once  the  sign  and  the 
reward  of  ethical  superiority  "No  question,"  argued  a  Puri- 
tan pamphleteer,  k'but  it  1  riches  1  should  be  the  portion 
rather  of  the  godly  than  of  the  wicked,  were  it  good  for 
them,  for  godliness  hath  the  promises  of  this  life  as  well 
as  of  the  life  to  come  "  '  ~  The  demonstration  that  distress 
is  a  proof  of  demerit,  though  a  singular  commentary  on  the 
lives  of  Christian  saints  and  sages,  has  always  been  popular 
with  the  prosperous  By  the  lusty  plutocracy  of  the  Restora- 
tion, roaring  after  its  meat,  and  not  indisposed,  if  it  could 
not  find  it  elsewhere,  to  seek  it  from  God,  it  was  welcomed 
with  a  shout  of  applause. 

A  society  which  reverences  the  attainment  of  riches  as 


222  THL   PURITAN    MOVEMENT 

the  supreme  felicity  will  naturally  be  disposed  to  regard  the 
poor  as  damned  in  the  next  world,  if  only  to  justify  itself 
for  making  their  life  a  hell  in  this.  Advanced  by  men  of 
religion  as  a  tonic  for  the  soul,  the  doctrine  of  the  danger 
of  pampering  poverty  was  hailed  by  the  rising  school  of 
Political  Arithmeticians  as  a  sovereign  cure  for  the  ills  of 
society.  For,  if  the  theme  of  the  moralist  was  that  an  easy- 
going indulgence  undermined  character,  the  theme  of  the 
economist  was  that  it  was  economically  disastrous  and  finan- 
cially ruinous.  The  Poor  Law  is  the  mother  of  idleness, 
"men  and  women  growing  so  idle  and  proud  that  they  will 
not  work,  but  lie  upon  the  parish  wherein  they  dwell  for 
maintenance."  It  discourages  thrift;  "if  shame  or  fear  of 
punishment  makes  him  earn  his  dayly  bread,  he  will  do  no 
more;  his  children  are  the  charge  of  the  parish  and  his  old 
age  his  recess  from  labour  or  care."  It  keeps  up  wages,  since 
"ft  encourages  wilful  and  evil-disposed  persons  to  impose 
what  wages  they  please  upon  their  labours ;  and  herein  they 
are  so  refractory  to  reason  and  the  benefit  of  the  nation 
that,  when  corn  and  provisions  are  cheap,  they  will  not 
work  for  less  wages  than  when  they  were  dear  "  5 '  To  the 
landowner  who  cursed  the  poor-rates,  and  the  clothier  who 
grumbled  at  the  high  cost  of  labor,  one  school  of  religious 
thought  now  brought  the  comforting  assurance  that  moral- 
ity itself  would  be  favored  by  a  reduction  of  both. 

As  the  history  of  the  Poor  Law  in  the  nineteenth  century 
was  to  prove,  there  is  no  touchstone,  except  the  treatment 
of  childhood,  which  reveals  the  true  character  of  a  social 
philosophy  more  clearly  than  the  spirit  in  which  it  regards 
the  misfortunes  of  those  of  its  members  who  fall  by  the 
way.  Such  utterances  on  the  subject  of  poverty  were  merely 
one  example  of  a  general  attitude,  which  appeared  at  times 
to  consign  to  collective  perdition  almost  the  whole  of  the 
wage-earning  population.  It  was  partly  that,  in  an  age  which 
worshiped  property  as  the  foundation  of  the  social  order, 
the  mere  laborer  seemed  something  less  than  a  full  citizen. 
It  was  partly  the  result  of  the  greatly  increased  influence  on 
thought  and  public  affairs  acquired  at  the  Restoration  by 
the  commercial  classes,  whose  temper  was  a  ruthless  ma- 
terialism, determined  at  all  costs  to  conquer  world-markets 
from  France  and  Holland,  and  prepared  to  sacrifice  every 
other  consideration  to  their  economic  ambitions.  It  was 


THE   NEW   MEDICINE   FOR   POVERTY  223 

partly  that,  in  spite  of  a  century  of  large-scale  production 
in  textiles,  the  problems  of  capitalist  industry  and  of  a 
propertyless  proletariat  were  still  too  novel  for  their  essen- 
tial features  to  be  appreciated.  Even  those  writers,  like 
Baxter  and  Bunyan,  who  continued  to  insist  on  the  wicked- 
ness of  extortionate  prices  and  unconscionable  interest, 
rarely  thought  of  applying  their  principles  to  the  subject 
of  wages.  Their  social  theory  had  been  designed  for  an  age 
of  petty  agriculture  and  industry,  in  which  personal  rela- 
tions had  not  yet  been  superseded  by  the  cash  nexus,  and 
the  craftsman  or  peasant  farmer  was  but  little  removed  in 
economic  status  from  the  half-dozen  journeymen  or  laborers 
whom  he  employed.  In  a  world  increasingly  dominated  by 
great  clothiers,  iron-masters  and  mine-owners,  they  still  ad- 
hered to  the  antiquated  categories  of  master  and  servant, 
with  the  same  obstinate  indifference  to  economic  realities  as 
leads  the  twentieth  century  to  talk  of  employers  and  em- 
ployed, long  after  the  individual  employer  has  been  converted 
into  an  impersonal  corporation. 

In  a  famous  passage  of  the  Communist  Manifesto,  Marx 
observes  that  "the  bourgeoisie,  wherever  it  got  the  upper 
hand,  put  an  end  to  all  feudal,  patriarchal,  idyllic  relations, 
pitilessly  tore  asunder  the  motley  feudal  ties  that  bound  man 
to  his  t natural  superiors,'  and  left  remaining  no  other  bond 
between  man  and  man  than  naked  self-interest  and  callous 
cash  payment."  134  An  interesting  illustration  of  his  thesis 
might  be  found  in  the  discussions  of  the  economics  of  em- 
ployment by  English  writers  of  the  period  between  1660  and 
1760.  Their  characteristic  was  an  attitude  towards  the  new 
industrial  proletariat  noticeably  harsher  than  that  general  in 
the  first  half  of  the  seventeenth  century,  and  which  has  no 
modern  parallel  except  in  the  behavior  of  the  less  reputable 
of  white  colonists  towards  colored  labor.  The  denunciations 
of  the  "luxury,  pride  and  sloth"  ir>  of  the  English  wage- 
earners  of  the  seventeenth  and  eighteenth  centuries  are,  in- 
deed, almost  exactly  identical  with  those  directed  against 
African  natives  today.  It  is  complained  that,  compared  with 
the  Dutch,  they  are 'self-indulgent  and  idle;  that  they  want 
no  more  than  a  bare  subsistence,  and  will  cease  work  the 
moment  they  obtain  it;  that,  the  higher  their  wages,  the 
more— uso  licentious  are  they"  l  Ml— they  spend  upon  drink; 
that  high  prices,  therefore,  are  not  a  misfortune,  but  a  bless- 


224  THE    PURITAN    MOVEMENT 

ing;  since  they  compel  the  wage-earner  to  be  more  industri- 
ous; and  that  high  wages  are  not  a  blessing,  but  a  misfortune, 
since  they  merely  conduce  to  "weekly  debauches  " 

When  such  doctrines  were  general,  it  was  natural  that  the 
rigors  of  economic  exploitation  should  be  preached  as  a  pub- 
lic duty,  and.  with  a  few  exceptions,  the  writers  of  the 
period  differed  only  as  to  the  methods  by  which  severity 
could  most  advantageously  be  organized  Pollexfen  and 
Walter  Harris  thought  that  salvation  might  be  found  by 
reducing  the  number  of  days  kept  as  holidays  Bishop  Ber- 
keley, with  the  conditions  of  Ireland  before  his  eyes,  sug- 
gested that  "sturdy  beggars  should  .  .  be  seized  and  made 
slaves  to  the  public  for  a  certain  term  of  years  '  Thomas 
Alcock,  who  was  shocked  at  the  workman's  taste  for  snuff, 
tea  and  ribbons,  proposed  the  revival  of  sumptuary  legis- 
lation J  )7  The  writers  who  advanced  schemes  for  reformed 
workhouses,  which  should  be  places  at  once  of  punishment 
and  of  training,  were  innumerable.  All  were  agreed  that,  on 
moral  no  less  than  on  economic  grounds,  it  was  vital  that 
wages  should  be  reduced  The  doctrine  afterwards  expressed 
by  Arthur  Young,  when  he  wrote,  "every  one  but  an  idiot 
knows  that  the  lower  classes  must  be  kept  poor,  or  they 
will  never  be  industrious/' *  'b  was  the  tritest  commonplace 
of  Restoration  economists  It  was  not  argued,  it  was  ac- 
cepted as  self-evident 

When  philanthropists  were  inquiring  whether  it  might  not 
be  desirable  to  reestablish  slavery,  it  was  not  to  be  expected 
that  the  sufferings  of  the  destitute  would  wring  their  hearts 
with  social  compunction  The  most  curious  feature  in  the 
whole  discussion,  and  that  which  is  most  sharply  in  contrast 
with  the  long  debate  on  pauperism  carried  on  in  the  six- 
teenth century,  was  the  resolute  refusal  to  admit  that  society 
had  any  responsibility  for  the  causes  of  distress  Tudor 
divines  and  statesmen  had  little  mercy  for  idle  rogues.  But 
the  former  always,  and  the  latter  ultimately,  regarded  pau- 
perism primarily  as  a  social  phenomenon  produced  by 
economic  dislocation,  and  the  embarrassing  question  put  by 
the  genial  Harrison — "at  whose  handes  shall  the  bloude  of 
these  men  be  required?"  1%H<> — was  never  far  from  the  minds 
even  of  the  most  cynical.  Their  successors  after  the  Res- 
toration were  apparently  quite  unconscious  that  it  was  even 
conceivable  that  there  might  be  any  other  cause  of  poverty 


THE   NEW   MEDICINE   FOR  POVERTY  225 

than  the  moral  failings  of  the  poor.  The  practical  conclusion 
to  be  drawn  from  so  comfortable  a  creed  was  at  once  ex- 
tremely simple  and  extremely  agreeable.  It  was  not  to  find 
employment  under  the  Act  of  1601,  for  to  do  that  was  only 
"to  render  the  poor  more  bold."  It  was  to  surround  the 
right  to  relief  with  obstacles  such  as  those  contained  in  the 
Act  of  1662,  to  give  it,  when  it  could  not  be  avoided,  in  a 
workhouse  or  house  of  correction,  and,  for  the  rest,  to  in- 
crease the  demand  for  labor  by  reducing  wages. 

The  grand  discovery  of  a  commercial  age,  that  relief 
might  be  so  administered  as  not  merely  to  relieve,  but  also 
to  deter,  still  remained  to  be  made  by  Utilitarian  philoso- 
phers. But  the  theory  that  distress  was  due,  not  to  economic 
circumstances,  but  to  what  the  Poor  Law  Commissioners  of 
1834  called  "individual  improvidence  and  vice,"  was  firmly 
established,  and  the  criticism  on  the  Elizabethan  system 
which  was  to  inspire  the  new  Poor  Law  had  already  been 
formulated.  The  essence  of  that  system  was  admirably  ex- 
pressed a  century  later  by  a  Scottish  divine  as  "the  principle 
that  each  man,  simply  because  he  exists,  holds  a  right  on 
other  men  or  on  society  for  existence. "  14°  Dr.  Chalmers' 
attack  upon  it  was  the  echo  of  a  note  long  struck  by  Puri- 
tan moralists.  And  the  views  of  Dr.  Chalmers  had  impressed 
themselves  on  Nassau  Senior,141  before  he  set  his  rr-md  to 
that  brilliant,  influential  and  wildly  unhistorical  Report, 
which,  after  provoking  something  like  a  rebellion  in  the 
north  of  England,  was  to  be  one  of  the  pillars  of  the  social 
policy  of  the  nineteenth  century. 

It  would  be  misleading  to  dwell  on  the  limitations  of 
Puritan  ethics  without  emphasizing  the  enormous  contribu- 
tion of  Puritanism  to  political  freedom  and  social  progress. 
The  foundation  of  democracy  is  the  sense  of  spiritual  inde- 
pendence which  nerves  the  individual  to  stand  alone  against 
the  powers  of  this  world,  and  in  England,  where  squire  and 
parson,  lifting  arrogant  eyebrows  at  the  insolence  of  the 
lower  orders,  combined  to  crush  popular  agitation,  as  a 
menace  at  once  to  society  and  to  the  Church,  it  is  probable 
that  democracy  owes  more  to  Nonconformity  than  to  any 
other  single  movement.  The  virtues  of  enterprise,  diligence 
and  thrift  are  the  indispensable  foundation  of  any  complex 
and  vigorous  civilization.  It  was  Puritanism  which,  by  in- 
vesting them  with  a  supernatural  sanction,  turned  them 


226  THE    PURITAN    MOVEMENT 

from  an  unsocial  eccentricity  into  a  habit  and  a  religion. 
Nor  would  it  be  difficult  to  find  notable  representatives  of 
the  Puritan  spirit  in  whom  the  personal  authority,  which  was 
the  noblest  aspect  of  the  new  ideal,  was  combined  with  a 
profound  consciousness  of  social  solidarity,  which  was  the 
noblest  aspect  of  that  which  it  displaced  Firmm  the  philan- 
thropist, and  Sellers  the  Quaker,  whom  Owen  more  than  a 
century  later  hailed  as  the  father  of  his  doctrines,  were 
pioneers  of  Poor  Law  reform.  The  Society  of  Friends,  in  an 
age  when  the  divorce  between  religion  and  social  ethics  was 
almost  complete,  met  the  prevalent  doctrine,  that  it  was 
permissible  to  take  such  gain  as  the  market  offered,  by  in- 
sisting on  the  obligation  of  good  conscience  and  forbearance 
in  economic  transactions,  and  on  the  duty  to  make  the  hon- 
orable maintenance  of  the  brother  in  distress  a  common 
charge.142 

The  general  climate  and  character  of  a  country  are  not 
altered,  however,  by  the  fact  that  here  and  there  it  has  peaks 
which  rise  into  an  ampler  air.  The  distinctive  note  of  Puri- 
tan teaching  was  different.  It  was  individual  responsibility, 
not  social  obligation.  Training  its  pupils  to  the  mastery  of 
others  through  the  mastery  of  self,  it  prized  as  a  crown 
of  glory  the  qualities  which  arm  the  spiritual  athlete  for  his 
solitary  contest  with  a  hostile  world,  and  dismissed  concern 
with  the  social  order  as  the  prop  of  weaklings  and  the  Capua 
of  the  soul.  Both  the  excellences  and  the  defects  of  that 
attitude  were  momentous  for  the  future  It  is  sometimes 
suggested  that  the  astonishing  outburst  of  industrial  activ- 
ity which  took  place  after  1760  created  a  new  type  of  eco- 
nomic character,  as  well  as  a  new  system  of  economic 
organization.  In  reality,  the  ideal  which  was  later  to  carry 
all  before  it,  in  the  person  of  the  inventor  and  engineer  and 
captain  of  industry,  was  well  established  among  Englishmen 
before  the  end  of  the  seventeenth  century.  Among  the  numer- 
ous forces  which  had  gone  to  form  it,  some  not  inconsider- 
able part  may  reasonably  be  ascribed  to  the  emphasis  on 
the  life  of  business  enterprise  as  the  appropriate  field  for 
Christian  endeavor,  and  on  the  qualities  needed  for  success 
in  it,  which  was  characteristic  of  Puritanism.  These  qualities, 
and  the  admiration  of  them,  remained,  when  the  religious 
reference,  and  the  restraints  which  it  imposed,  had  weak- 
ened or  disappeared. 


CHAPTER  V 

Conclusion 

"Ther  is  a  certaine  man  that  shortly  after  my  fyrst  sermon,  beynge 
asked  if  he  had  bene  at  the  sermon  that  day,  answered,  yea  I  praye 
you,  said  he,  how  lyked  you  hym?  Mary,  sayed  he,  even  as  I  lyked 
hym  alwayes — a  seditious  fellow  " 

LATIMBR,  Seven  Serin  om  before  King  Edward  VI. 

SOCIETIES,  like  individuals,  have  their  moral  crises  and  their 
spiritual  rpvn^jHnrK  The  student  can  observe  the  results 
which  these  cataclysms  produce,  but  he  can  hardly  without 
presumption  attempt  to  appraise  them,  for  it  is  at  the  fire 
which  they  kindled  that  his  own  small  taper  has  been  lit. 
The  rise  of  a  naturalistic  science  of  society,  with  all  its  mag- 
nificent promise  of  fruitful  action  and  of  intellectual  light; 
the  abdication  of  the  Christian  Churches  from  departments 
of  economic  conduct  and  social  theory  long  claimed  as  their 
province;  the  general  acceptance  by  thinkers  of  a  scale  of 
ethical  values,  which  turned  the  desire  for  pecuniary  gain 
from  a  perilous,  if  natural,  frailty  into  the  idol  of  philoso- 
phers and  the  mainspring  of  society — such  movements  are 
written  large  over  the  history  of  the  tempestuous  age  which 
lies  between  the  Reformation  and  the  full  light  of  the 
eighteenth  century.  Their  consequences  have  been  worked 
into  the  very  tissue  of  modern  civilization  Posterity  still 
stands  too  near  their  source  to  discern  the  ocean  into  which 
these  streams  will  flow 

In  an  historical  age  the  relativity  of  political  doctrines  is 
the  tritest  of  commonplaces.  But  social  psychology  contin- 
ues too  often  to  be  discussed  in  serene  indifference  to  the 
categories  of  time  and  place,  and  economic  interests  are  still 
popularly  treated  as  though  they  formed  a  kingdom  over 
which  the  Zeitgeist  bears  no  sway.  In  reality,  though  in- 
herited dispositions  may  be  constant  from  generation  to 
generation,  the  system  of  valuations,  preferences  and  ideals 
— the  social  environment  within  which  individual  character 
functions — is  in  process  of  continuous  change,  and  it  is  in 
the  conception  of  the  place  to  be  assigned  to  economic  in- 
terests in  the  life  of  society  that  change  has  in  recent 
centuries  been  most  comprehensive  in  its  scope,  and  most 

227 


228  CONCLUSION 

sensational  in  its  consequences.  The  isolation  of  economic 
aims  as  a  specialized  object  of  concentrated  and  systematic 
effort,  the  erection  of  economic  criteria  into  an  independent 
and  authoritative  standard  of  social  expediency,  are  phe- 
nomena which,  though  familiar  enough  in  classical  antiquity, 
appear,  at  least  on  a  grand  scale,  only  at  a  comparatively 
recent  date  in  the  history  of  later  civilizations  The  conflict 
between  the  economic  outlook  of  East  and  West,  which  im- 
presses the  traveller  today,  finds  a  parallel  in  the  contrast 
between  medieval  and  modern  economic  ideas,  which  strikes 
the  historian. 

The  elements  which  combined  to  produce  that  revolution 
are  too  numerous  to  be  summarized  in  any  neat  formula. 
But,  side  by  side  with  the  expansion  of  trade  and  the  rise 
of  new  classes  to  political  power,  there  was  a  further  cause, 
which,  if  not  the  most  conspicuous,  was  not  the  least  funda- 
mental. It  was  the  contraction  of  the  territory  within  which 
the  spirit  of  religion  was  conceived  to  run.  The  criticism 
which  dismisses  the  concern  of  Churches  with  economic 
relations  and  social  organization  as  a  modern  innovation 
finds  little  support  in  past  history.  What  requires  explana- 
tion is  not  the  view  that  these  matters  are  part  of  the  prov- 
ince of  religion,  but  the  view  that  they  are  not  When  the 
age  of  the  Reformation  begins,  economics  is  still  a  branch 
of  ethics,  and  ethics  of  theology;  all  human  activities  are 
treated  as  falling  within  a  single  scheme,  whose  character  is 
determined  by  the  spiritual  destiny  of  mankind,  the  appeal 
of  theorists  is  to  natural  law,  not  to  utility,  the  legitimacy 
of  economic  transactions  is  tried  by  reference,  less  to  the 
movements  of  the  market,  than  to  moral  standards  derived 
from  the  traditional  teaching  of  the  Christian  Church,  the 
Church  itself  is  regarded  as  a  society  wielding  theoretical, 
and  sometimes  practical,  authority  in  social  affairs.  The 
secularization  of  political  thought ,  which  was  to  be  the  work 
of  the  next  two  centuries,  had  profound  reactions  on  social 
speculation,  and  by  the  Restoration  the  whole  perspective, 
at  least  in  England,  has  been  revolutionized  Religion  has 
been  converted  from  the  keystone  which  holds  together  the 
social  edifice  into  one  department  within  it,  and  the  idea 
of  a  rule  of  right  is  replaced  by  economic  expediency  as  the 
arbiter  of  policy  and  the  criterion  of  conduct.  From  a  spirit- 
ual being,  who,  in  order  to  survive,  must  devote  a  reasonable 


CONCLUSION  229 

attention  to  economic  interest,  man  seems  sometimes  to  have 
become  an  economic  animal,  who  will  be  prudent,  never- 
theless, if  he  takes  due  precautions  to  assure  his  spiritual 
well-being. 

The  result  is  an  attitude  which  forms  so  fundamental  a 
part  of  modern  political  thought,  that  both  its  precarious 
philosophical  basis,  and  the  contrast  which  it  offers  with  the 
conceptions  of  earlier  generations,  are  commonly  forgotten. 
Its  essence  is  a  dualism  which  regards  the  secular  and  the 
religious  aspects  of  life,  not  as  successive  stages  within  a 
larger  unity,  but  as  parallel  and  independent  provinces, 
governed  by  different  laws,  judged  by  different  standards, 
and  amenable  to  different  authorities.  To  the  most  repre- 
sentative minds  of  the  Reformation,  as  of  the  Middle  Ages, 
a  philosophy  which  treated  the  transactions  of  commerce 
and  the  institutions  of  society  as  indifferent  to  religion  would 
have  appeared,  not  merely  morally  reprehensible,  but  intel- 
lectually absurd.  Holding  as  their  first  assumption  that  the 
ultimate  social  authority  is  the  will  of  God,  and  that  tem- 
poral interests  are  a  transitory  episode  in  the  life  of  spirits 
which  are  eternal,  they  state  the  rules  to  which  the  social 
conduct  of  the  Christian  must  conform,  and,  when  circum- 
stances allow,  organize  the  discipline  by  which  those  rules 
may  be  enforced.  By  their  successors  in  the  eighteenth  cen- 
tury the  philosophy  of  Indifferentism,  though  rarely  formu- 
lated as  a  matter  of  theory,  is  held  in  practice  as  a  truism 
which  it  is  irrational,  if  not  actually  immoral,  to  question, 
since  it  is  in  the  heart  of  the  individual  that  religion  has  its 
throne,  and  to  externalize  it  in  rules  and  instructions  is  to 
tarnish  its  purity  and  to  degrade  its  appeal  Naturally, 
therefore,  they  formulate  the  ethical  principles  of  Christian- 
ity in  terms  of  a  comfortable  ambiguity,  and  rarely  indicate 
with  any  precision  their  application  to  commerce,  finance, 
and  the  ownership  of  property  Thus  the  conflict  between 
religion  and  those  natural  economic  ambitions  which  the 
thought  of  an  earlier  age  had  regarded  with  suspicion  is 
suspended  by  a  truce  which  divides  the  life  of  mankind 
between  them  The  former  takes  as  its  province  the  individ- 
ual soul,  the  latter  the  intercourse  of  man  with  his  fellows 
in  the  activities  of  business  and  the  affairs  of  society.  Pro- 
vided that  each  keeps  to  his  own  territory,  peace  is  assured. 
They  cannot  collide,  for  they  can  never  meet. 


230  CONCLUSION 

History  is  a  stage  where  forces  which  are  within  human 
control  contend  and  cooperate  with  forces  which  are  not. 
The  change  of  opinion  described  in  these  pages  drew  nour- 
ishment from  both.  The  storm  and  fury  of  the  Puritan 
revolution  had  been  followed  by  a  dazzling  outburst  of 
economic  enterprise,  and  the  transformation  of  the  material 
environment  prepared  an  atmosphere  in  which  a  judicious 
moderation  seemed  the  voice  at  once  of  the  truest  wisdom 
and  the  sincerest  piety.  But  the  inner  world  was  in  motion 
as  well  as  the  outer.  The  march  of  external  progress  woke 
sympathetic  echoes  in  hearts  already  attuned  to  applaud  its 
triumph,  and  there  was  no  consciousness  of  an  acute  tension 
between  the  claims  of  religion  and  the  glittering  allurements 
of  a  commercial  civilization,  such  as  had  tormented  the  age 
of  the  Reformation. 

It  was  partly  the  natural,  and  not  unreasonable,  diffidence 
of  men  who  were  conscious  that  traditional  doctrines  of 
social  ethics,  with  their  impracticable  distrust  of  economic 
motives,  belonged  to  the  conditions  of  a  vanished  age,  but 
who  lacked  the  creative  energy  to  state  them  anew,  in  a 
form  applicable  to  the  needs  of  a  more  complex  and  mobile 
social  order.  It  was  partly  that  political  changes  had  gone 
far  to  identify  the  Church  of  England  with  the  ruling  aris- 
tocracy, so  that,  while  in  France,  when  the  crash  came,  many 
of  the  lower  clergy  threw  in  tneir  lot  with  the  tiers  etat,  in 
England  it  was  rarely  that  the  officers  of  the  Church  did  not 
echo  the  views  of  society  which  commended  themselves  to 
the  rulers  of  the  State.  It  was  partly  that,  to  one  important 
body  of  opinion,  the  very  heart  of  religion  was  a  spirit  which 
made  indifference  to  the  gross  world  of  external  circum- 
stances appear,  not  a  defect,  but  an  ornament  of  the  soul. 
Untrammelled  by  the  silken  chains  which  bound  the  Estab- 
lishment, and  with  a  great  tradition  of  discipline  behind 
them,  the  Nonconformist  Churches  might  seem  to  have  pos- 
sessed opportunities  of  reasserting  the  social  obligations  of 
religion  with  a  vigor  denied  to  the  Church  of  England.  What 
impeded  their  utterance  was  less  a  weakness  than  the  most 
essential  and  distinctive  of  their  virtues.  Founded  on  the  re- 
pudiation of  the  idea  that  human  effort  could  avail  to  win 
salvation,  or  human  aid  to  assist  the  pilgrim  in  his  lonely 
quest,  they  saw  the  world  of  business  and  society  as  a  bat- 
tlefield, across  which  character  could  march  triumphant  to 


CONCLUSION  231 

its  goal,  not  as  crude  materials  waiting  the  architect's  hand 
to  set  them  in  their  place  as  the  foundations  of  the  King- 
dom of  Heaven.  It  did  not  occur  to  them  that  character  is 
social,  and  society,  since  it  is  the  expression  of  character, 
spiritual  Thus  the  eye  is  sometimes  blinded  by  light  itself. 

The  certainties  of  one  age  areJJie  problems  of  the  next. 
Few  will  refuse  their  admiration  TO  the  magnificent  concep- 
tion of  a  community  penetrated  from  apex  to  foundation  by 
the  moral  law,  which  was  the  inspiration  of  the  great  re- 
formers, not  less  than  of  the  better  minds  oi  the  Middle  Ag^b. 
But,  in  order  to  subdue  the  tough  world  of  material  inter- 
ests, it  is  necessary  to  have  at  least  so  much  sympathy  w.th 
its  tortuous  ways  as  is  needed  to  understand  them  The 
Prince  of  Darkness  has  a  right  to  a  courteous  hearing  and  a 
fair  trial,  and  those  who  will  not  give  him  his  due  are  wont 
to  find  that,  in  the  long  run,  he  turns  the  tables  by  taking 
his  due  and  something  over.  Common  sense  and  a  respect 
for  realities  are  not  less  graces  of  the  spirit  than  moral 
zeal  The  paroxysms  of  virtuous  fury,  with  which  the  chil- 
dren of  light  denounced  each  new  victory  of  economic  enter- 
prise as  yet  another  stratagem  of  Mammon,  disabled  them 
for  the  staff -work  of  their  campaign,  which  needs  a  cool 
head  as  well  as  a  stout  heart  Their  obstinate  refusal  to  re- 
vise old  formulae  in  the  light  of  new  facts  exposed  them  help- 
less to  a  counter-attack,  in  which  the  whole  fabric  of  their 
philosophy,  truth  and  fantasy  alike,  was  overwhelmed  to- 
gether They  despised  knowledge,  and  knowledge  destroyed 
them. 

Few  can  contemplate  without  a  sense  of  exhilaration  the 
splendid  achievements  of  practical  energy  and  technical  skill, 
which,  from  the  latter  part  of  the  seventeenth  century,  were 
transforming  the  face  of  material  civilization,  and  of  which 
England  was  the  daring,  if  not  too  scrupulous,  pioneer.  If, 
however,  economic  ambitions  are  good  servants,  they  are 
bad  masters  Harnessed  to  a  social  purpose,  they  will  turn 
the  mill  and  grind  the  corn.  But  the  question,  to  what  end 
the  wheels  revolve,  still  remains;  and  on  that  question  the 
naive  and  uncritical  worship  of  economic  power,  which  is 
the  mood  of  unreason  too  often  engendered  in  those  whom 
that  new  Leviathan  has  hypnotized  by  its  spell,  throws  no 
light.  Its  result  is  not  seldom  a  world  in  which  men  com- 


232  CONCLUSION 

mand  a  mechanism  that  they  cannot  fully  use,  and  an  or- 
ganization which  has  every  perfection  except  that  of  motion. 

Er  nennt's  Vernunft  und  braucht's  alletn, 
Nur  tierischer  als  jedes  Tier  zu  sein 

The  shaft  of  Mephistopheles,  which  drops  harmless  from 
the  armor  of  Reason,  pierces  the  lazy  caricature  which  mas- 
querades beneath  the  sacred  name,  to  flatter  its  followers 
with  the  smiling  illusion  of  progress  won  from  the  mastery 
of  the  material  environment  by  a  race  too  selfish  and  super- 
ficial to  determine  the  purpose  to  which  its  triumphs  shall 
be  applied.  Mankind  may  wring  her  secrets  from  nature, 
and  use  their  knowledge  to  destroy  themselves;  they 
may  command  the  Ariels  of  heat  and  motion,  and  bind 
their  wings  in  helpless  frustration,  while  they  wrangle  over 
the  question  of  the  master  whom  the  imprisoned  genii  shall 
serve.  Whether  the  chemist  shall  provide  them  with  the 
means  of  life  or  with  the  tri-nitro-toluol  and  poison  gas, 
whether  industry  shall  straighten  the  bent  back  to  crush  it 
beneath  heavier  burdens,  depends  on  an  act  of  choice  be- 
tween incompatible  ideals,  for  which  no  increase  in  the  ap- 
paratus of  civilization  at  man's  disposal  is  in  itself  a  sub- 
stitute. Economic  efficiency  is  a  necessary  element  in  the 
life  of  any  sane  and  vigorous  society,  and  only  the  incorri- 
gible sentimentalist  will  depreciate  its  significance.  But  to 
convert  efficiency  from  an  instrument  into  a  primary  object 
is  to  destroy  efficiency  itself  For  the  condition  of  effective 
action  in  a  complex  civilization  is  cooperation.  And  the  con- 
dition of  cooperation  is  agreement,  both  as  to  ends  to  which 
effort  should  be  applied,  and  the  criteria  by  which  its  suc- 
cess is  to  be  judged. 

Agreement  as  to  ends  implies  the  acceptance  of  a  stand- 
ard of  values,  by  which  the  position  to  be  assigned  to  dif- 
ferent objects  may  be  determined.  In  a  world  of  limited 
resources,  where  nature  yields  a  return  only  to  prolonged 
and  systematic  effort,  such  a  standard  must  obviously  take 
account  of  economic  possibilities.  But  it  cannot  itself  be 
merely  economic,  since  the  comparative  importance  of  eco- 
nomic and  of  other  interests — the  sacrifice,  for  example,  of 
material  goods  worth  incurring  in  order  to  extend  leisure, 
or  develop  education,  or  humanize  toil — is  precisely  the  point 


CONCLUSION  233 

on  which  it  is  needed  to  throw  light  It  must  be  based  on 
some  conception  of  the  requirements  of  human  nature  as 
a  whole,  to  which  the  satisfaction  of  economic  needs  is  evi- 
dently vital,  but  which  demands  the  satisfaction  of  other 
needs  as  well,  and  which  can  organize  its  activities  on  a 
rational  system  only  in  so  far  as  it  has  a  clear  apprehension 
of  their  relative  significance.  "Whatever  the  world  thinks," 
wrote  Bishop  Berkeley,  "he  who  hath  not  much  meditated 
upon  God7  the  human  mind  and  the  summum  bonum  may 
possibly  make  a  thriving  earthworm,  but  will  most  indubi- 
tably make  a  sorry  patriot  and  a  sorry  statesman."  The  phi- 
losopher of  today,  who  bids  us  base  our  hopes  of  progress 
on  knowledge  inspired  by  love,  does  not  differ  from  the 
Bishop  so  much,  perhaps,  as  he  would  wish.  The  most  ob- 
vious facts  are  the  most  easily  forgotten  Both  the  existing 
economic  order,  and  too  many  of  the  projects  advanced 
for  reconstructing  it,  break  down  through  their  neglect  of 
the  truism  that,  since  even  quite  common  men  have  souls, 
no  increase  in  material  wealth  will  compensate  them  for 
arrangements  which  insult  their  self-respect  and  impair 
their  freedom  A  reasonable  estimate  of  economic  organiza- 
tion must  allow  for  the  fact  that,  unless  industry  is  to  be 
paralyzed  by  recurrent  revolts  on  the  part  of  outraged  hu- 
man nature,  it  must  satisfy  criteria  which  are  not  purely 
economic  A  reasonable  view  of  its  possible  modifications 
must  recognize  that  natural  appetites  may  be  purified  or  re- 
strained, as,  in  fact,  in  some  considerable  measure  they  al- 
ready have  been,  by  being  submitted  to  the  control  of  some 
larger  body  of  interests.  The  distinction  made  by  the  phi- 
losophers of  classical  antiquity  between  liberal  and  servile 
occupations,  the  medieval  insistence  that  riches  exist  for 
man,  not  man  for  riches,  Ruskin's  famous  outburst,  "there 
is  no  wealth  but  life,"  the  argument  of  the  Socialist  who 
urges  that  production  should  be  organized  for  service,  not 
for  profit,  are  but  different  attempts  to  emphasize  the  in- 
strumental character  of  economic  activities  by  reference  to 
an  ideal  which  is  held  to  express  the  true  nature  of  man. 
Of  that  nature  and  its  possibilities  the  Christian  Church 
was  thought,  during  the  greater  part  of  the  period  discussed 
in  these  pages,  to  hold  by  definition  a  conception  distinc- 
tively its  own.  It  was  therefore  committed  to  the  formula- 
tion of  a  social  theory,  not  as  a  philanthropic  gloss  upon  the 


234  CONCLUSION 

main  body  of  its  teaching,  but  as  a  vital  element  in  a  creed 
concerned  with  the  destiny  of  men  whose  character  is 
formed,  and  whose  spiritual  potentialities  are  fostered  or 
starved,  by  the  commerce  of  the  market-place  and  the  in- 
stitutions of  society.  Stripped  of  the  eccentricities  of  period 
and  place,  its  philosophy  had  as  its  center  a  determination 
to  assert  the  superiority  of  moral  principles  over  economic 
appetites,  which  have  their  place,  and  an  important  place, 
in  the  human  scheme,  but  which,  like  other  natural  appe- 
tites, when  flattered  and  pampered  and  overfed,  bring  ruin 
to  the  soul  and  confusion  to  society.  Its  casuistry  was  an 
attempt  to  translate  these  principles  into  a  code  of  practical 
ethics,  sufficiently  precise  to  be  applied  to  the  dusty  world 
of  warehouse  and  farm.  Its  discipline  was  an  effort,  too  often 
corrupt  and  pettifogging  in  practice,  but  not  ignoble  in  con- 
ception, to  work  the  Christian  virtues  into  the  spotted  tex- 
ture of  individual  character  and  social  conduct.  That  prac- 
tice was  often  a  sorry  parody  on  theory  is  a  truism  which 
should  need  no  emphasis  But  in  a  world  where  principles 
and  conduct  are  unequally  mated,  men  are  to  be  judged  by 
their  reach  as  well  as  by  their  grasp — by  the  ends  at  which 
they  aim  as  well  as  by  the  success  with  which  they  attain 
them.  The  prudent  critic  will  try  himself  by  his  achieve- 
ment rather  than  by  his  ideals,  and  his  neighbors,  living  and 
dead  alike,  by  their  ideals  not  less  than  by  their  achieve- 
ment. 

Circumstances  alter  from  age  to  age,  and  the  practical 
interpretation  of  moral  principles  must  alter  with  them.  Few 
who  consider  dispassionately  the  facts  of  social  history  will 
be  disposed  to  deny  that  the  exploitation  of  the  weak  by 
the  powerful,  organized  for  the  purposes  of  economic  gain, 
buttressed  by  imposing  systems  of  law,  and  screened  by  dec- 
orous draperies  of  virtuous  sentiment  and  resounding  rhet- 
oric, has  been  a  permanent  feature  in  the  life  of  most  com- 
munities that  the  world  has  yet  seen.  But  the  quality  in 
modern  societies  which  is  most  sharply  opposed  to  the  teach- 
ing ascribed  to  the  Founder  of  the  Christian  Faith  lies  deep- 
er than  the  exceptional  failures  and  abnormal  follies  against 
which  criticism  is  most  commonly  directed.  It  consists  in 
the  assumption,  accepted  by  most  reformers  with  hardly 
less  naivete  than  by  the  defenders  of  the  established  order, 
that  the  attainment  of  material  riches  is  the  supreme  object 


CONCLUSION  23$ 

of  human  endeavor  and  the  final  criterion  of  human  success. 
Such  a  philosophy,  plausible,  militant,  and  not  indisposed, 
when  hard  pressed,  to  silence  criticism  by  persecution,  may 
triumph  or  may  decline  What  is  certain  is  that  it  is  the 
negation  of  any  system  of  thought  or  morals  which  can, 
except  by  a  metaphor,  be  described  as  Christian.  Compro- 
mise is  as  impossible  between  the  Church  of  Christ  and  the 
idolatry  of  wealth,  which  is  the  practical  religion  of  cap- 
italist societies,  as  it  was  between  the  Church  and  the  State 
idolatry  of  the  Roman  Empire. 

"Modern  capitalism/'  writes  Mr.  Keynes,  "is  absolutely 
irreligious,  without  internal  union,  without  much  public 
spirit,  often,  though  not  always,  a  mere  congeries  of  pos- 
sessors and  pursuers."  It  is  that  whole  system  of  appetites 
and  values,  with  its  deification  of  the  life  of  snatching  to 
hoard,  and  hoarding  to  snatch,  which  now,  in  the  hour  of 
its  triumph,  while  the  plaudits  of  the  crowd  still  ring  in  the 
ears  of  the  gladiators  and  the  laurels  are  still  unfaded  on 
their  brows,  seems  sometimes  to  leave  a  taste  as  of  ashes  on 
the  lips  of  a  civilization  which  has  brought  to  the  conquest 
of  its  material  environment  resources  unknown  in  earlier 
ages,  but  which  has  not  yet  learned  to  master  itself.  It  was 
against  that  system,  while  still  in  its  supple  and  insinuating 
youth,  before  success  had  caused  it  to  throw  aside  the  mask 
of  innocence,  and  while  its  true  nature  was  unknown  even 
to  itself,  that  the  saints  and  sages  of  earlier  ages  launched 
their  warnings  and  their  denunciations.  The  language  in 
which  theologians  and  preachers  expressed  their  horror  of 
the  sin  of  covetousness  may  appear  to  the  modern  reader 
too  murkily  sulphurous,  their  precepts  on  the  contracts  of 
business  and  the  disposition  of  property  may  seem  an  im- 
practicable pedantry.  But  rashness  is  a  more  agreeable  fail- 
ing than  cowardice,  and,  when  to  speak  is  unpopular,  it  is 
less  pardonable  to  be  silent  than  to  say  too  much.  Posterity 
has,  perhaps,  as  much  to  learn  from  the  whirlwind  eloquence 
with  which  Latimer  scourged  injustice  and  oppression  as 
from  the  sober  respectability  of  the  judicious  Paley — who 
himself,  since  there  are  depths  below  depths,  was  regarded 
as  a  dangerous  revolutionary  by  George  III. 


NOTES 

PREFACE  TO  19  ^  7  EDITION 

1  References  to  some  of  the  earlier  literature  will  be  found  in  the 
notes  on  subsequent  chapters    The  following  list  of  recent  books  and 
articles  is  not  exhaustive,  but  it  mav   be  of  some  use  to  those  inter- 
ested in  the  subject. 

E  Troeltcch,  The  Social  Teaching  of  the  Christian  Churches,  2  vols., 
London,  1931  (Eng  trans  by  Olive  Wyon)  of  his  Die  Soziallehren  der 
Chruthchcn  Kirchen  und  Grupp(n,  1912),  Max  Weber,  The  Prot- 
estant Ethic  and  the  Spirit  of  Capitalism,  London,  1930  (Eng  trans, 
by  Talcott  Parsons  of  Die  Protestantische  Ethik  und  der  Geist  des 
Kapitahsmus  in  "Archiv  fur  Sozialwissenschaft  und  Sozialpolitik," 
vols.  xx  (1904)  and  xxi  (1905),  later  reprinted  in  Gesammelte  Auf- 
salze  zur  Rehgionssoziologie,  3  vols  ,  Tubingen,  1921)  ,  H  Hauser,  Les 
debuts  du  Capitahsme,  Pans,  1927,  chap  li  (Les  Idees  economiques 
de  Calvin") ,  B  Groethuysen,  Ongmes  de  V esprit  bourgeois  en  France, 
Pans,  1927;  Margaret  James,  Social  Problems  and  Policy  during  the 
Puritan  Revolution,  1640  1660,  London,  1930,  Isabel  Grubb,  Quaker- 
ism and  Industry  before  1800,  London,  1930,  W  J  Warner,  The 
Wedeyun  Movement  in  the  Industrial  Revolution,  London,  1930;  R. 
Pascal,  The  Social  Basis  of  the  German  Reformation,  London,  1933; 
H  M  Robertson,  The  Rise  of  Economic  Individualism,  Cambridge, 
1913,  A  Fanfam,  Le  Origmi  dello  Spirito  Capitahstico  tn  Italia, 
Milan,  19,53,  and  Cattolici\mo  e  Protfstantenmo  nella  Formaztone 
Stonca  del  Capitahsmo,  Milan,  1934  (Eng;  trans  Catholicism,  Prot- 
estantism and  Capitalism,  London,  1935),  J  Brodrick,  S  J.,  The 
Economic  Morals  of  the  Jesuits,  London,  1934,  E  D  Bebb,  Non- 
conformity and  Social  and  Economic  Life,  1660-1800,  London,  1935 
The  articles  include  the  following  M  Halbwachs,  Les  Origmes  Puri- 
taines  du  Capitahsme  Moderne"  (Revue  d'hutoire  et  de  Philoso- 
phic rehgieuses,  March-April,  1925)  and  "Economistes  et  Historiens, 
Max  Weber,  une  vie,  un  oeuvre"  (Annales  d'Histoire  £conomique  et 
Sociale,  No.  1,  1929)  ;  H  See,  "Dans  quelle  mesure  Puritams  et  Juifs 
ont-ils  contnbue  au  Progres  du  Capitahsme  Moderne'*"  (Revue 
Htstonque,  t  CLV,  1927),  Kemper  Fullerton,  "Calvinism  and  Cap- 
italism" (Harvard  Theological  Review,  July  1928) ;  F  H  Knight, 
''Historical  and  Theoretical  Issues  in  the  Problem  of  Modern  Cap- 
italism" (Journal  of  Economic  and  Business  History,  November 
1Q28)  ,  Talcott  Parsons,  "Capitalism  in  Recent  German  Literature" 
(Journal  of  Political  Economy,  December  1928  and  February  1929) ; 
P.  C  Gordon  Walker,  "Capitalism  and  the  Reformation"  (Economic 
History  Review,  November  1937). 

2  For    Weber's    life    and    personality,    see    Marianne    Weber,    Max 
Weber,  ein  Lebensbild,  Tubingen,  1926,  and  Karl  Jaspers,  Max  Weber, 
Deutschvs  Wesen  im  politischen  Denken,  im  Forschen  und  PhUoso- 
phieren,   Oldenburg,    1932 

8  Max  Weber,  The  Protestant  Ethic  and  the  Spirit  of  Capitalism, 
Eng  trans ,  p.  183. 

237 


238  NOTES 

4  H.  M.  Robertson,  Aspects  of  the  Rise  of  Economic  Individualism, 
p  xii. 

8  Weber,  op    cit ,  p    26 
"Weber,  op   cit ,  p   183. 

7  Ibid,  p    183,  and  note  118  on  chap   v    "it  would  have  been  easy 
to  proceed          .  to   a  regular  construction   which   logically    deduced 
everything  characteristic  of  modern  culture  from  Protestant  nation- 
alism   But  that  sort  ol  thing  may  be  left  to  the  type  of  dilettante 
who  believes  in  the  unity  of  the  group  mind  and  its  redu ability  to  a 
single   formula  "  "Spiritual"  is  my  rendering  of  the  almost  untrans- 
latable " spintualistische  kausale  " 

8  See  below,  note  32  on  chap    iv,  pp.  247-8,  and  Max  Weber,  op 
cit ,  pp.  3-11 

"  Weber,  op  cit  ,  197-8  A  chapter  expanding  the  same  criticism  is 
contained  in  H  M  Robertson,  Aspects  of  the  Rise  of  Economic  In- 
dividualism, pp  S7-87  The  best  treatment  of  the  subject  is  that  of 
Brentano,  Die  Anfange  des  modernen  Kapitahsmus,  1916,  pp  117-^7, 
and  Der  Wirtschaftendc  Mensch  in  der  Geschichte,  Leipzig,  1923,  pp 
363  sq 

10  See  H    M    Robertson,   op    cit  ,  pp    88-110  and   133-67,   and  J 
Brodnck,  S   J  ,  The  Economic  Morah  of  the  Jesuits,  which,  in  addi- 
tion to  correcting   Robertson's   errors,   contains   the   be^t   account   of 
the  economic  teaching  of  the   Jesuits  available  in  English 

11  Eg,   H     Wiskemann,   Darstellung    der   in   Deutsthland   zur   Zeit 
der     Reformation     henschenden     Nationalokonomischen     Amichten, 
Leipzig,  1861,   F    Engels,  Socialism,  Utopian  and  Scientific,  London, 
1892,  Introduction,   Alfred  Marshall,  Principles   of  Economics,   1898, 
chap  [II,  W    Cunningham,  Christianity  and  Social  Questions,  London, 
1910  (see  below,  note  33  on  chap    iv)    The  last  work,  though  pub- 
lished seven  years  after  the  appearance  of  Weber's  articles,  does  not 
refer  to  them,  nor  is  its  argument  similar  to  theirs 

12  E  g  ,  H    M    Robertson,  op    cit ,  p    xi    "Many  writers  have  taken 
advantage  of  an  unpopularity  of  Capitalism  in  the  twentieth  century 
to  employ  them   [sc    the  theories  ascribed  to  Weber]   in  attacks  on 
Calvinism,  or  on  other  branches  of  religion  "  The  only  Guy  Fawkes 
of  the  gang — apart,  of  course,  from  myself — detected  by  Mr    Robert- 
son actually  firing  the  tram  appears  to  be  that  implacable  incendiary, 
Mr    Aldous   Huxley     "Infected,"    like    the    arch-conspirator,    Weber", 
"with  a  deep  hatred  of  Capitalism/'  we  stand  with  him  condemned  of 
"a   general   tendency   to   undermine   the   basis   of   Capitalist   society" 
(ibid,  pp   207-8).  The  guilty  secret  is  out  at  last 

1SH  Pirenne,  Les  Perwdes  de  I'Histoire  Sociale  due  Capitalisme, 
1914. 

CHAPTER   I 

1  J  B  Say,  Court  complet  d'Economic  politique  pratique,  vol  vi, 
1829,  pp.  351-2. 

2R  Torrens,  An  Essay  on  the  Production  of  Wealth,  1821,  Preface, 
p.  xiii. 

3  Lloyd  George  at  Portmadoc  (Times,  June  16,  1921) 

4  J    A    Froude,  Revival  of  Romanism,  in  Short  Studies  on  Great 
Subjects,  3rd  ser ,   1877,  p    108 


NOTES  ON   CHAPTER  I  239 

*  J.  N.  Figgis,  From  Genon  to  Grotius,  1916,  pp    21  seqq. 

6  Locke,  Two  Treatises  on  Government,  bk   ii,  chap,  ix,  §124. 

7  Nicholas  Oresme,   c.1320-82,   Bishop   of   Lisieux   from    1377.  His 
Tractatus  de  engine,  natura,  jure  et  mutatwnibus  monetarum  was 
probably  written  about  1360   The  Latin  and  French  texts  have  been 
edited   by   Wolowski    (Paris,   1864),   and   extracts   are   translated  by 
A.  E.  Monroe,  Early  Economic  Thought,  1924,  pp   81-102    Its  signifi- 
cance is  discussed  shortly  bv  Cunningham,  Growth  of  English  Indus- 
try and  Commerce,  Early  and  Middle  Ages  (4th  ed  ,  1905,  pp   354-9), 
and  by  Wolowski  in  his  introduction   The  date  of  De  Usuns  of  Lau- 
rentius  de  Rodolfis  was  1403;  a  short  account  of  his  theories  as  to 
the  exchanges  will  be  found  in  E    Schreiber,  Die  Wolkwirthschaft- 
licfon  Anschauungen  der  Scholastik  seit  Thomas  v    Aqum,  1913,  pp. 
211-17.  The  most  important  works  of  St   Antonmo  (1389-1459,  Arch- 
bishop of  Florence,  1446)  are  the  Summa  Theologica,  Summa  Con- 
fesstonalis,  and  De  Uwns    Some  account  of  his  teaching  is  given  by 
Carl  Ilgner,  Die  wolkswirthschnfthchen  Amchauungen  Antomm   von 
Florcnz,  1904;  Schreiber,  op    cit ,  pp    217-23,  and  Bede  Jarrett,  St. 
Antomno  and  Mediaeval  Economics,  1914    The  full  title  of  Baxter's 
work  is  A  Christian  Directory:  a  Summ  of  Practical  Theologie  and 
Cases  of  Conscience. 

8  See  Chap    IV,  p.  206 

"Benvenuto  da  Imola,  Comentum  super  Dantis  Comoediam  (ed 
Lacaita),  vol  i,  p  579;  "Qui  facit  usuram  vadit  ad  infernum;  qui 
non  facit  vadit  ad  inopiam"  (quoted  by  G  G  Coulton,  Social  Life  tn 
Britain  from  the  Conquest  to  the  Reformation,  1919,  p.  342). 

10Lanfranc,  Elucidanum,  lib  ii,  p.  18  (in  Opera,  ed  'j.  A  Giles). 
See  also  Vita  Sancti  Guidonis  (Bollandtsts'  Acta  Sanctorum,  Septem- 
ber, vol  iv,  p  43 )  "Mercatura  raro  aut  nunquam  ab  aliquo  dm  sine 
crimine  exercen  potuit " 

11  B    L.  Manning,  The  People's  Faith  in  the  Time  of  Wyclif,  1919, 
p.   186. 

12  Aquinas,  Summa  Theologica,  2a  2**,  div.  I,  Q.  Hi,  art   viii 
18  Ibid  ,  la  2«,  div.  i,  Q  xciv,  art  ii 

14  The  Bull   Unam  Sanctam  of  Boniface  VIII 

15  John  of  Salisbury,  Polycraticus  (ed  C    C   I   Webb),  lib    v,  cap. 
ii    ("Est  autem  res  publica,   sicut   Plutarco   placet,   corpus  quoddam 
quod  divini  munens  beneficio  ammatur"),  and  lib  vi,  cap.  x,  where 
the  analogy  is  worked  out  in  detail   For  Henry  VIII's  chaplain  sec 
Starkey,   A    Dialogue    between    Cardinal   Pole    and    Thomas    Lupstt 
(Early  English  Text  Society,  Extra  Ser  ,  no    xxxu,  1878) 

10  Chaucer,  The  P^rsone's  Tale,  §  66 

17  On  the  Seven  Deadly  Sins,  chap,  xix   (Select  English   Works  of 
John  Wychf,  ed    T    Arnold,  vol.  lii,  1871,  p.  145). 

18  John  of  Salisbury,  op  cit ,  lib   vi,  cap  x:  "Tune  autem  totius  rei 
pubhcae  salus  mcolumis  praeclaraque  erit,  si  supenora  membra  se  im- 
pendant  inferioribus  et  inferiora  superioribus  pari  jure  respondeant, 
ut  singula  sint  quasi  aliorum  ad  invicem  membra  " 

^Wyclif,  op.  cit.,  chaps,  ix,  x,  xi,  xvii,  passim  (Works  of  Wyclif. 
ed.  T.  Arnold,  vol  iii,  pp  130,  131,  132,  134,  143). 

80  See,  e.g.,  A.  Doren,  Studien  aus  der  Florentiner  Wirthschaftsge- 
schichte,  1901,  vol.  i,  chaps,  v,  vii.  His  final  verdict  (p.  458)  is;  "Man 


240  NOTES 

kann  es  getrost  aussprechen  es  gibt  wohl  keine  Penodc  in  der  WeH- 
geschichte,  m  der  die  naturhche  Uebermacht  des  Kapitals  uber  die 
besitz-  und  kapitallose  Handarbeit  rucksichtsloser,  freier  von  sitthchen 
und  rechtlichen  Bedenken,  naiver  in  ihrer  sclbstverstadhchen  Konse- 
quenz  gewaltet  hatte,  und  bis  m  die  entferntesten  Folgen  zur  Geltung 
gebracht  worden  ware,  als  in  der  Blutezeit  der  Florentmer  Tuchin- 
dustrie "  The  picture  drawn  by  Pirenne  of  the  textile  industry  in 
Flanders  (Belgian  Democracy  Its  Early  History,  trans  by  J.  V 
Saunders,  1Q15,  pp  128-34)  is  somewhat  similar 

121  In  Jan  12Q8/Q  there  was  held  a  "parliament  of  carpenters  at 
Milehende,  where  they  bound  themselves  by  a  corporal  oath  not  to 
observe  a  certain  ordinance  or  provision  made  bv  the  Mayor  and  Al- 
dermen touching  their  craft,"  and  m  the  following  March  a  "parlia- 
ment of  smiths'  was  formed,  with  a  common  chest  (Calendar  of 
Early  Mayor's  Court  Rolls  of  the  City  of  London,  12Q8-1307,  ed 
A  H  Thomas,  1Q24,  pp  25,  33-34) 

~~  The  figures  for  Paris  are  the  estimate  of  Martin  Saint-Leon 
(Hutotre  des  Copoiatiom  de  Meticn,  3rd  ed  ,  1022,  pp  21°-20,  224, 
226)  ,  those  for  Frankfurt  are  given  by  Bucher  (Die  Bevolkeiung  von 
Frankiurt  am  Mam  im  XIV  und  \V  Jahrhundert,  1S86,  pp  1CH,  116, 
605)  They  do  not  include  apprentices,  and  must  not  be  pressed  too 
far  The  conclusion  of  Martin  Saint-Leon  is  UI1  est  certain  qu'au 
moyen  age  (abstraction  faite  des  villes  de  Flandre)  il  n'existait  pas 
encore  un  proletariat,  le  nombre  des  ouvners  ne  depassant  guere  ou 
n'atteignant  meme  pas  celui  des  maitres"  (op  cit ,  p  227  n  )  The 
towns  of  Italy  should  be  added,  as  an  exception,  to  those  of  Flanders, 
and  in  any  case  the  statement  is  not  generally  true  of  the  later  Middle 
Ages,  when  there  was  certainly  a  wage-earning  proletariat  in  Ger- 
many also  (sec  Lamprecht,  Zum  Verstandms  der  wirthschafthchen 
und  wztalen  Wandlungen  in  Deutschland  vom  14  znm  16  lahrhun- 
dert,  in  the  Zeitschnft  for  Sozial-  und  Wtrthichajtgeuhtchte,  vol  i, 
pp  101-263),  and  even,  though  on  a  smaller  scale,  in  England 

w  The  Crete  Sentence  of  Curs  Expouned,  chap  xxvni  (Select  Eng- 
lish Works  of  Wyclif,  ed.  T  Arnold,  vol  m,  p  3V>)  The  passage  con- 
tains comprehensive  denunciations  of  all  sorts  of  combination,  in 
particular,  gilds,  "men  of  sutel  craft,  as  fre  masons  and  othere,"  and 
"marchaumtis,  grocens,  and  vitilens"  who  "conspiren  wickidly  togidre 
that  noon  of  hem  schal  bic  over  a  certeyn  pns,  though  the  thing  that 
thei  bien  be  moche  more  worthi"  (ibid  ,  pp  333,  334) 

Wyclif 's  argument  is  of  great  interest  and  importance  It  is  (1), 
that  such  associations  for  mutual  aid  are  unnecessary  No  special  in- 
stitutions are  needed  to  promote  fraternity,  since,  quite  apart  from 
them,  all  members  of  the  community  are  bound  to  help  each  other, 
"Alle  the  goodnes  that  is  in  thes  glides  eche  man  owith  for  to  do  bi 
comyn  fraternytc  of  Cnsendom,  by  Goddis  comaundemcnt  "  (2)  That 
combinations  are  a  conspiracy  against  the  public  Both  doctrines  were 
points  in  the  case  for  the  sovereignty  of  the  unitarv  State,  and  both 
were  to  play  a  large  part  in  subsequent  history  They  were  used  by 
the  absolutist  statesmen  of  the  sixteenth  century  as  an  argument  for 
State  control  over  industry,  in  place  of  the  obstructive  torpor  of  gilds 
and  boroughs,  and  by  the  individualists  of  the  eighteenth  century  as 
an  argument  for  free  competition  The  line  of  thought  as  to  the  re- 


NOTES    ON    CHAPTER   I  241 

lation  of  minor  associations  to  the  State  runs  from  Wyclif  to  Turgot, 
Rousseau,  Adam  Smith,  the  \ct  of  the  Legislative  Assembly  in  1792 
forbidding  trade  unions  ("Les  citoyens  de  meme  etat  ou  profession, 
les  ouvner  et  compagnons  d'un  art  quelconque  ne  pourront  .  .  for- 
mer des  reglements  sur  leurs  pretendus  interets  communs"),  and  the 
English  Combination  Acts 

24  Kayser  Sigtnunds  Reformation  alter  Stande  des  Heihgen  Rb- 
mischen  Reichs,  printed  by  Goldast,  Collectio  Constitutionum  1m- 
permltum,  1713,  vol  iv,  pp  170-200  Its  probable  date  appears  to  be 
about  14^7  It  is  discussed  shortly  by  J  S  Schapiro,  Social  Reform 
and  the  Reformation,  1900,  pp  03-9 

-"'Martin  Saint-Leon,  op  at  ,  p  187  The  author's  remark  is  made 
a  propos  ol  a  ruling  of  1270,  fixing  minimum  rates  for  textile  workers 
in  Pans  It  appears,  however,  to  be  unduly  optimistic  The  fact  that 
minimum  rates  were  fixed  for  textile  workers  must  not  be  taken  as 
evidence  that  that  policy  was  common,  tor  in  England,  and  probably 
m  France,  the  textile  trades  received  special  treatment,  and  minimum 
rates  were  fixed  for  them,  while  maximum  rates  were  fixed  for  other, 
and  much  more  numerous,  bodies  of  workers  What  ic  true  is  that  the 
medieval  assumption  with  regard  to  wages,  as  with  regard  to  the 
much  more  important  question  of  prices,  was  that  it  was  possible  to 
bring  them  into  agreement  with  an  objective  standard  of  equity, 
which  did  not  reflect  the  mere  play  of  economic  forces 

*°  "The  Cardinals'  Gospel,"  translated  from  the  Carmina  Burana 
by  G  G  Coulton,  in  A  Medieval  Garner,  1010,  p  347 

2~  Printed  from  the  Carmina  Buiana  by  S  Gaselec,  An  Anthology 
of  Medieval  Latin,  1925,  pp  58-9 

~'s  Innocent  IV  gave  them  in  1248  the  title  of  "Romans  ecclesiae  filii 
speciales"  (Ehrenberg,  Das  Zeitalter  der  Fugget,  1806,  vol  11,  p  66). 

20  For  Grosstete  see  Matthew  Paris,  Chronica  Maiota,  vol  v,  pp. 
404-5  (where  he  is  reported  as  denouncing  the  Cahurbines,  ''whom  in 
our  time  the  holy  fathers  and  teachers  had  driven  out  of  France, 

but  who  have  been  encouraged  and  protected  by  the  Pope  in  England, 
which  did  not  formerly  suffer  from  this  pestilence"),  and  F  S  Steven- 
son, Robert  Growteste,  Bishop  of  Lincoln,  180Q,  pp  101-4  For  the 
bishop  of  London  and  the  Cahoi  sines  see  Matthew  Pans,  Chron. 
Maj  ,  vol  m,  pp  331-2  A  useful  collection  of  references  on  the  whole 
subject  is  given  by  Ehrenberg,  op  at  ,  vol  n,  pp  64-8 

M  Re  girt  rum  FpHtolaritm  J  Peckham,  vol  i,  p  18,  July  1279  (trans- 
lated by  Coulton,  Social  Life  in  Britain  from  the  Conquest  to  the 
Reformation,  p  345) 

31  For  cases  of  clerical  usury  see  Selden  Society,  vol    v,  1891,  Leet 
Jurisdiction  in  the  City  of  Norwich,  ed   W.  Hudson,  p   35,  Hist.  MSS. 
Conim  ,    MSS     of    the   Marquis    of   Lothian,    1905,   p     26,    and   Th 
Bonnin,  Regestrum  Vivtationum  Odonis  Rigaldi,  1852,  p   35    See  also 
note   88    (below) 

32  The  Chapter  of  Notre-Dame  appears  to  have  lent  money  at  in- 
terest to  the  citizens  of  Paris  (A    Luchaire,  Social  France  at  the  time 
of  Phthp  Augustus,  translated  by  E    B    Krehbiel,  1912,  p    130)    For 
the  bishop's  advice  to  the  usurer,  see  ibid ,  p    166 

88  From  a  letter  of  St  Bernard,  cl!25,  printed  by  Coulton,  A  Me- 
atoeval  Garner,  pp.  68-73 


242  NOTES 

84  Aquinas,  De  Regimine  Principium,  lib.  ii,  cap    i-vii,  where  the 
economic  foundations  of  a  State  are  dscussed 

85  Aquinas,  Summa  Theol ,  2a  2re,  Q.  Ixxxiii,  art   vi   For  St    Anto- 
nino's  remarks  to  the  same  purpose,  see  Jarrett,  St.  Antonmo  and 
Mediaeval  Economics,  p.  59. 

^Gratian,  Decretum,  pt   ii,  causa  xii,  Q   i,  c   ii,  §  1. 

87  A  good  account  of  St  Antonmo's  theory  of  property  is  given  by 
Ilgner,  Die  Volkswirthschafthchen  Anschauungen  Antonms  von 
Florenz,  chap,  x 

38  uSed  si  esset  bonus  legislator  m  patria  indigente,  deberet  locare 
pro  pretio  magno  huiusmodi  mercatores  .  .  .  et  non  tantum  eis  et 
famihse  sustentationem  necessanum  in  venire,  sed  etiam  mdustnam,  pe- 
ritiam,  et  pencula  omma  locare,  ergo  etiam  hoc  possunt  ipsi  in  ven- 
dendo"  (quoted  Schreiber,  Die  Volkswirthschafthchen  Anschauungen 
der  Scolastik  seit  Thomas  v  Aquin,  p  154) 

8W  Henry  of  Ghent,  Aurea  Quodhbeta,  p  42b  (quoted  Schreiber,  op 
cit.,  p.  135 

40  Gratian,  Decretum,  pt.   1,  dist    Ixxxvm,  cap    xi 

41  Aquinas,  Summa  Theol ,  2a  2ffi,  Q  Ixxvh,  art  iv 

**Ibid.  Trade  is  unobjectionable,  "cum  aliquis  negotiationi  intendit 
propter  pubhcam  utihtatem,  ne  scilicet  res  necessanae  ad  vitam  patriae 
desint,  et  lucrum  expetit,  non  quasi  finem,  sed  quasi  stipendium 
laboris." 

43  Henry  of  Langenstem,  Tractatus  btpartibus  dc  contractibus  emp- 
tionis  et  vendtttonis,  i,  12   (quoted  Schreiber,  op    cit  ,  p.   197). 

44  See  Chap    II,  §  n 

45  Examples  of  these  stories  are  printed  by  Coulton,  A   Mediaeval 
Garner,  1910,  pp    212-  LS,  298,  and  Social  Life  in  England  from  the 
Conquest  to  the  Reformation,  1919,  p    346. 

46  The  facts  are  given  by  Arturo  Segre,  Storia  del  Commercio,  vol. 
i,  p  223   For  a  fuller  account  of  credit  and  money-lending  in  Florence, 
see  Doren    Studien  aus  der  Florentiner  Wuthwhaftsgeschichte,  vol    i, 
pp    173-209 

4'  Bruno  Kuske,  Quellen  zur  Geschvchte  des  Kolner  Handels  und  Ver- 
kehrs  im  Mittelalter,  vol  ih,  1923,  pp  197-8 

48  Early  English  Text  Society,  The  Coventry  Leet  Book,  ed  M  D. 
Harris,  1907-13,  p  544 

48  Wyclif ,  On  the  Seven  Deadly  Sins,  chap  xxiv  (Works  of  IVycltf, 
ed.  T  Arnold,  vol  m,  pp  154-5)  The  word  rendered  "loan"  is  "leeve" 
[?  leene]  in  the  text 

80  For  examples  of  such  cases  see  Early  Chancery  Proceedings,  Bdle 
Ixiv,  nos  291  and  1089,  Bdle.  xxxvii,  no   38,  Bdle,  xlvi,  no   307   They 
are  discussed  in  some  detail  in  my  introduction  to  Thomas  Wilson's 
Discourse  upon  Usury,  1925,  pp  28-9 

81  Hist    MSS    Com,  of  Marquis   of  Lothian,   p    27,   Selden   Soc., 
Leet  Jurisdiction  in  the  City  of  Norwich,  p    35 

62  Aquinas,  Summa  Theol.,  la  2®,  Q  xcv,  art.  ii 

M0w  the  Seven  Deadly  Sins,  chap  xxiv  (Works  of  Wyclif,  ed.  T. 
Arnold,  vol.  ni,  p.  153).  "Bot  men  of  la  we  and  marchauntis  and 
chapmen  and  vitelers  synnen  more  in  avarice  then  done  pore  laboreres. 
And  this  token  hereof;  for  now  ben  thei  pore,  ond  now  ben  the! 
ful  riche,  for  wronges  that  thei  done." 


NOTES    ON    CHAPTER   I  243 

64 Eg,  ^gidius  Lessinus,  De  Usuris,  cap  ix,  pt  r  "Tantum  res 
estimatur  juste,  quantum  ad  utihtatem  possidentis  refertur,  et  tan- 
turn  juste  valet,  quantum  sine  fraude  vcndi  potest  Omnis  trans- 
latio  farta  hbera  voluntate  dommorum  juste  fit,"  Johannes  Buri- 
danus,  Qucestiones  supei  deccm  hbros  Ethicorum  Anstotelh,  v,  23-  "Si 
iptui  rem  suam  sic  alienat,  jpse  secundum  suam  estimationem  non 
dammficatur,  sed  lucratur,  igitur  non  injustum  patitur."  Both  writ- 
ers are  discussed  by  Schreiber  (op  cit  ,  pp  161-71  and  177-91)  The 
theory  of  Bundanus  appears  extraordinarily  modern,  but  he  is  care- 
ful to  emphasize  that  prices  should  be  fixed  "secundum  utilitatem  et 
necessitatem  totius  communitatis/'  not  "penes  necessitatem  ementis 
vel  vendentis  " 

r>r>  St  Antonio,  Summa  Theologica,  pars  n,  tit  i,  cap  vin,  §  I,  and 
chap  xvi,  §  iii.  An  account  of  St  Antonmo's  theory  of  prices  is  given 
b^  i  Inner  Die  volkswirthschafthchen  AmchdiMrren  An<onms  von 
Florenz,  chap,  iv;  Jarrett,  St  Antonino  and  Mediaeval  Economics , 
and  bchrciber,  op  at,  pp  217-73  Us  interest  consists  m  the  at- 
tempts to  maintain  the  principle  of  the  just  price,  while  making 
allowance  for  practical  necessities 

r"'Henrv  of  Lnnc;enstein,  Tantnt^\  bipartitus  de  contractibus  emp- 
tionis  et  vendttioms,  i,  11,  12  (quoted  Schreiber  op  cit  ,  pp  198-200). 

57  For  these  examples  see  Cat  of  Early  Mayors  Court  Rolls  of  the 
City  of  London,  ed  A  H  Thomas,  pp  259-60;  Records  of  the  City 
of  'Norwich,  ed  W  Hudson  and  J  C.  Tingey,  vol  i,  1906,  p  227; 
Cal  of  Early  Mayor's  Court  Rolls,  p  132,  J  M  Wilson,  The  Wor- 
cester Liber  Albus,  1920,  pp  100-200,  212-13  The  question  of  the 
legitimacy  of  rent-charges  and  of  the  profits  of  partnership  has  been 
fully  discussed  by  Max  Neumann,  Geschichte  des  Wuchers  m  Deutsch- 
land  (1865),  and  b^  \*hley,  Economic  Theory  See  also  G  O'Brien, 
An  Essay  on  Medieval  Economic  Teaching  (1920),  and  G  G  Coul- 
ton,  \n  Episode  in  Canon  Law  (in  History,  July  1021),  where  the 
difficult  question  raised  by  the  Decretal  Namganti  is  discussed. 

'<h  Bcrnardi  Papiensn  ^umma  Decretahum  (i«d  K  A  L)  Laspeyres, 
1860)  ,  lib  v  tit  xv 

50  Eg,  ^gidius  Lessinus,  De  Uwns,  chap  ix,  pt  n  "Etiam  res  fu- 
thra3  per  tempora  non  sunt  tanta?  estimations,  sicut  ea?dcm  collectae 
in  instanti,  nrc  lantam  utilitatem  mferunt  possidentibus,  propter  quod 
oportet,  quod  smt  minons  estimations  secundum  justitiam  " 

60  O'Brien,  (op  at.}  appears,  unless  I  misunderstand  him,  to  take 
this  view 

"  Poli1*<*,  T  m  ad  fin  12^Sb  S»e  Who  sard  "Barren  Metal"?  by 
E  Cannan,  W  D  Ross,  etc  ,  in  Economica,  June  1922,  pp  105-7. 

62  Innocent  IV,  Apparatus,  lib    v,  De   Usuris. 

'''For  Italy,  see  Arturo  Se«re,  Storm  del  Commerno,  vol  i,  pp.  179- 
91,  and  for  France,  P  Boissonadc,  Le  Travail  dans  I'Europe  chre- 
tienne  an  Moyen  Age,  1021,  pp  206-9,  212-13  Both  emphasize  the 
financial  relations  of  the  Papacy 

64  Eg,  Council  of  Aries,  314,  Nicaea,  325,  Laodicea,  372,  and  many 
others 

65  Corpus  Juris  Canomci,  Decretal    Greg   IX,  lib   v,  tit   xix,  cap.  i 
**  Ibid,  cap    hi 

67  Ibid,  Sexti  Decretal,  lib    v    tit    v,  cap    i,  ii 


244  NOTES 

88  Ibid.,  Clemen tinarum,  lib.  v,  tit.  v,  cap.  i. 

^The  passages  referred  to  in  this  paragraph  are  as  follows.  Corp. 
Jur.  Can ,  Decretal.  Greg  IX,  lib  v,  tit.  xix,  cap.  ix,  iv,  x,  xhi,  xv, 
ii,  v,  vi. 

70  A  Formulary  oj  the  Papal  Penitentiary  in  the  Thirteenth  Century, 
ed.  H    C    Lea,  1892,  Nos.  xcn,  clxxvm  (2),  cixxix. 

71  Raimundi  de  Penna-jorti  Summa  Pastoralis  (Ravaisson,  Catalogue 
General  des  MSS.  des  Bibliotheques  pubhques  des  Departements,  1849, 
vol.  i,  pp.  592  seqq}.  The  archdeacon  is  to  inquire     "Whether  [the 
priest]  feeds  his  flock,  assisting  those  who  are  in  need  and  above  all 
those  who  are  sick   Works  of  mercy  also  are  to  be  suggested  by  the 
archdeacon,  to  be  done  by  him  for  their  assistance.  If  he  cannot  fully 
accomplish  them  out  of  his  own  resources,  he  ought,  according  to  his 
power,  to  use  his  personal  influence  to  get  from  others  the  means  of 
carrying  them  out          Inquiries  concerning  the  parishioners  are  to  be 
made,  both  from  the  priest  and  from  others  among  them  worthy  of 
credence,  who,  if  necessary,  are  to  be  summoned  for  the  purpose  to  the 
presence  of  the  archdeacon,  as  well  as  from  the  neighbours,  with  re- 
gard to  matters  which  appear  to  need  correction.  First,  inquiry  is  to  be 
made  whether  there  are  notorious  usurers,  or  persons  reputed  to  be 
usurers,  and  what  sort  of  usury  they  practise,  whether  any  one,  that 
is  to  say,  lends  money  or  anything  else  .     .  on  condition  that  he  re- 
ceive anything  above  the  principal,  or  holds  any  pledge  and  takes 
profits  from  it  in  excess  of  the  principal,  or  receives  pledges  and  uses 
them  in  the  meantime  for  his  own  gam,  .  .  .  whether  he  holds  horses 
in  pledge  and  reckons  in  the  cost  of  their  fodder  more  than  they  can 
eat  or  whether  he  buys  anything  at  a  much  lower  price  than  it 
is  worth,  on  condition  that  the  seller  can  take  it  back  at  a  fixed  term 
on  paying  the  price,  though  the  buyer  knows  that  he  (the  seller)  will 
not  be  able  to  do  so;  or  whether  he  buys  anything  for  a  less  price 
than  it  is  worth,  because  he  pays  before  receiving  the  article,  for  ex- 
ample, standing  corn;  or  whether  any  one,  as  a  matter  of  custom  and 
without  express  contract,  is  wont  to  take  payment  above  the  princi- 
pal, as  the  Cahorsines  do  Further,  it  is  to  be  inquired  whether 
he  practises  usury  cloaked  under  the  guise  of  a  partnership  (nomine 
societatis  palhatam),  as  when  a  man  lends  money  to  a  merchant,  on 
condition  that  he  be  a  partner  in  the  gains,  but  not  in  the  losses. 
.  .  .  Further,  whether  he  practises  usury  cloaked  under  the  guise  of  a 
penalty   [for  non-payment  at  a  given  date!  is  not  that  he  may  be 
paid  more  quickly,  but  that  he  may  be  paid  more   Further,  whether 
he  practises  usury  in  kind,  as  when  a  rich  man,  who  has  lent  money, 
will  not  receive  from  a  poor  man  any  money  above  the  principal,  but 
agrees  that  he  shall  work  two  days  in  his  vineyard,  or  something  of 
the  kind  Further,  whether  he  practises  usury  cloaked  by  reference  to 
a  third  party,  as  when  a  man  will  not  lend  himself,  but  has  a  friend 
whom  he  induces  to  lend   When  it  has  been  ascertained  how  many 
persons  in  that  parish  are  notorious  for  usury   of  this  kind,   their 
names  are  to  be  reduced  to  writing,  and  the  archdeacon  is  to  proceed 
against  them  in  virtue  of  his  office,  causing  them  to  be  cited  to  his 
court  on  a  day  fixed,  either  before  himself  or  his  responsible  offical, 
even  if  there  is  no  accuser,  on  the  ground  that  they  are  accused  by 
common  report.  If  thev  are  convicted,  either  because  their  offence  is 


NOTES    ON    CHAPTER    I  245 

evident,  or  by  their  own  confession,  or  by  witnesses,  he  is  to  punish 
them  as  he  thinks  best  If  they  cannot  be  directly  convicted,  by 

reason  of  their  manifold  shifts  and  stratagems,  nevertheless  their  ill 
fame  as  usurers  can  easily  be  established  .  .  If  the  archdeacon  pro- 
ceed with  caution  and  diligence  against  their  wicked  doings,  they  will 
hardly  be  able  to  hold  ther  own  or  to  escape— it,  that  is  he  vex 

them  with  trouble  and  expense,  and  humiliate  them,  by  frequently 
serving  citations  on  them  and  assigning  several  different  days  for  their 
trial,  so  that  by  trouble,  expense,  loss  of  time,  and  all  manner  of 
confusion  they  may  be  induced  to  repent  and  submit  themselves  to 
the  discipline  of  the  Church  " 

u  E  Martene  and  U  Durand,  Thesaurus  novus  Anecdotorum,  1717, 
vol  iv,  pp  6-96  seqq 

7iPecock,  The  Represser  of  over-much  blaming  of  the  Clergy,  ed. 
C  Babington,  1860,  pt  i,  chap  in,  pp  15-16  His  words  show  both 
the  difficulties  which  confronted  ecclesiastical  teaching  and  the  at- 
tempts to  overcome  them  "I  preie  thee  seie  to  me  where  in  Holi 
Scripture  is  \oven  the  hundnd  parti  of  the  techmg  upon  matnmonie 
which  y  teche  in  a  book  mad  upon  Matnmomc,  and  in  the  1irste  partie 
of  Crist  en  religioun  Seie  to  me  also  where  m  Holi  Scripture  is 
yoven  the  hundnd  part  of  the  techng  which  is  yoven  upon  usure  in 
the  thndde  parti  of  the  book  yclepid  The  filling  of  the  tiij  tables; 
and  yit  al  thilk  hool  techmg  yoven  upon  usure  in  the  now  named 
book  is  Iitil  ynough  or  ouer  litlc  for  to  leerne,  knowe  and  have  suffi- 
cienth  into  manni^  behove  and  into  Goddis  trewe  service  and  lawe 
kepmg  what  is  to  be  Icerned  and  kunnen  aboute  usure,  as  to  reeders 
and  studiers  ther  yn  it  muste  needis  be  open  Is  ther  eny  more  writen 
of  usure  in  al  the  Newe  Testament  save  this,  Luke  vi,  'Gevc  ve  loone, 
hoping  no  thing;  ther  of,'  and  al  that  is  of  usure  writen  in  the  Gold 
Testament  favounth  rather  usure  than  it  reproveth  How  evere,  ther- 
fore,  schulde  eny  man  seie  that  the  sufficient  leernyng  and  kunnyng 
of  usure  or  of  the  vertu  contrane  to  usure  is  groundid  m  Holi  Scrip- 
ture? Howe  evere  sch.il  thilk  htil  now  rehercid  clausul,  Luke  vi,  be 
sufficient  for  to  answere  and  assoile  alle  the  harde  scrupulose  doutis 
and  questiouns  which  al  dai  han  neede  to  be  assoiled  ih  mennis  bar- 
genyngis  and  cheffarmgis  togidere?  Erh  man  having  to  do  with  suche 
questiouns  mai  soone  se  that  Holi  Writt  geveth  htil  or  noon  light 
thereto  at  al  Forwhi  al  that  Holi  Writt  seith  ther  to  is  that  he  for- 
bedith  usure,  and  therfore  al  that  mai  be  take  therbi  is  this,  that 
usure  is  unleeful,  but  though  y  bileeve  herbi  that  usure  is  unleeful, 
how  schal  y  wite  herbi  what  usure  is,  that  y  be  waar  for  to  not  do  it, 
and  whanne  in  a  bargcyn  is  usure,  though  to  summen  seemeth  noon, 
and  how  in  a  bargeyn  is  noon  usure  though  to  summen  ther  semeth 
to  be?" 

Perock's  defence  of  the  necessity  of  commentaries  on  the  teaching 
of  Scripture  was  the  real  answer  to  the  statement  afteruards  made 
by  Luther  that  the  text,  "Love  thy  neighbour  as  thyself,"  was  an  all- 
sufficient  guide  to  action  (see  Chap  II,  p  99)  Examples  of  teaching 
as  to  usury  contained  in  books  such  as  Pecock  had  in  mind  will  be 
found  in  Myrc's  Instructions  for  Parish  Priests  (Early  English  Text 
Society,  ed  E  Peacock  and  F.  J.  Furnivall,  1902),  the  Puptlla  Oculi, 


246  NOTES 

and  Dan  Michel's  Ayenbite  of  Inwyt  (Early  English  Text  Society,  ed 
R.  Morris,  1866). 

14  The  Catechism  of  John  Hamilton,  Archbishop  of  St  Andrews, 
1552,  ed.  T  G  Law,  1884,  pp  07-9  Under  the  seventh  command- 
ment are  denounced  "Fyfthe,  al  thay  that  defrauchs  or  spoulyeis  the 
common  geir,  agams  the  common  weill  for  lufe  of  their  awm  prvvate 
and  singulare  weill  Saxtlie,  all  usurans  and  ocknans  agam?  this  com- 
mand, that  wil  nocht  len  thair  geir  frelie,  hot  makis  conditione  of 
ockir,  aganis  the  command  of  Chnste  Sevmthe,  all  thay  quhilk  hais 
servandis  or  work  men  and  wyll  nocht  pay  theim  thair  fee  or  waige, 
accordyng  to  conclitioun  and  thair  deservyng,  quilk  syn,  as  sanct 
James  sayis,  cryis  vengeance  before  God  Auchthe,  all  thai  that  strykis 
cowyne  of  unlauchful  metall,  quhair  throuch  the  common  well  is 
hurt  and  skaithit  The  nynte,  all  Merchandis  that  sellis  corruppit  and 
cvyll  stufe  for  gude,  and  gyf  thay  or  ony  uther  in  bymg  or  selKng 
use  desait,  falsate,  parjune,  wran?  mettis  or  weychtis,  to  the  skaith  of 
thair  nychtbour,  thay  committ  gret  syn  agane  thi^  command  Nother 
can  we  clenge  fra  breakyng  of  this  command  all  kyndis  of  craftis  men 
quhilk  usis  nocht  thair  awm  craft  leillahe  and  trewlie  a?  thai  suld 
do  .  All  wrechis  that  wyl  be  ground  ryche  mcontynent,  quhay  be 
fraud,  falset,  and  gyle  twynnis  men  and  thair  geir,  quhay  may  keip 
thair  nychbour  fra  povertie  and  myschance  and  dois  it  nocht  Quha> 
takis  ouer  sair  mail,  ouer  mekle  feime  or  onv  blake  maillis  fra  thair 
tennands,  or  puttis  thair  cottans  to  ouir  sair  labouns,  quhair  throw 
the  tenentis  and  cottans  is  put  to  herschip  Quha  mvies  hi*  nych- 
bouris  gud  fortune,  ouir  byis  him  or  takis  his  geir  out  of  his  handis 
with  fair  hechtis,  or  prevent  him,  or  begyle5;  him  at  his  marchandis 
hand  "  The  detail  in  which  different  forms  of  commercial  sharp  prac- 
tice are  denounced  is  noticeable 

"See  eg  Matt  Pans,  Chron  May ,  vol  m,  pp  101-2,  for  the  case 
of  a  priest  who,  for  refusing  to  give  Christian  burial  to  an  excom- 
municate usurer,  is  seized  by  order  of  the  County  of  Brittany  and 
buried  alive,  bound  to  the  dead  man  See  also  Material  for  the  His- 
tory of  Thomas  Becket,  vol  v,  p  38 

Harduin,  Ada  Concihorum,  vol  vn,  pp  1017-20,  "Anno  praedicto 
[14851  diebus  Mercurn  et  Jovis  praedictis,  scilicet  ante  Ramos  Pal- 
marum,  ibidem  apud  Vicanum,  in  claustro  ecclesiae  de  Vicano,  coram 
domino  archiepiscopo,  et  mandata  sui,  personae  infrascriptse,  paro- 
chiani  de  Guorgonio,  qui  super  usuraria  pravitate  erant  quam  plun- 
num  diffamati,  coram  domino  propter  hoc  vocati  abjuraverunt  et 
per  mandatum  dommi  summas  mfrascnptas,  quas  se  confessi  fuerunt 
hubuisse  per  usuranam  pravitatem,  per  juramentum  suum  restituere 
promiserut,  et  stare  juri  super  his  coram  eo  Bertrandus  de  Faveriis 
abjuratus  usuras,  ut  praemittitur,  promisit  restituere  centum  sohdos 
monetae  antiquae '  quos,  prout  ipse  confessus  est,  habuerat  per  usura- 
rium  pravitatem  .  .  "  Thirty-six  more  cases  were  treated  in  this  way 

"Villani,  Cronica,  book  xii,  chap  Ivni  (ed  1823,  vol  vi,  p  142) 
Villani  complains  of  the  conduct  of  the  inquisitor-  "Ma  per  attignere 
danari,  d'ogni  piccola  parola  oziosa  che  alcuno  dicesse  per  iniquita 
contra  Iddio,  o  dicesse  che  usura  non  fosse  peccato  mortale,  o  simili 
parole,  condannava  in  grossa  somma  di  danari,  secondo  che  Tuomo 
era  ricco  " 


NOTES    ON    «"H  \?TER    I  247 

n  Constitutions  of  Clarendon,  cap  15  "Placita  de  debitis,  quae  fid« 
interposita  debentur,  vel  absquc  mterpositione  fidei,  smt  in  justitia 
regis  "  On  the  whole  subject  see  Pollock  and  Maitland,  History  of 
English  Law,  2nd  ed  ,  1808,  vol  11,  pp  197-202,  and  F  Makower, 
Constitutional  History  of  the  Church  of  England,  1705,  §  60. 

79  Cat  of  Early  Mavor's  Court  Roils  of  the  City  of  London,  ed.  A. 
H  Thomas,  pp  44,  88,  156,  235,  Selden  Soc  ,  Borough  Customs,  ed. 
M  Bateson,  vol  11,  1906,  pp  161  (London)  and  200-10  (Dublin); 
Records  of  Leicester,  ed  M  Bateson,  vol  ii,  1901,  p.  4Q  For  similar 
prohibitions  by  manorial  courts,  see  Htst  MSS.  Com  ,  MSS.  of  Mar- 
quis  of  Lothian,  p  28,  and  G  P  Scrope,  History  of  the  Manor  and 
Barony  of  Castl*  Combe,  1852,  p  238. 

**  Atinales  de  Burton,  p  256,  Wilkms,  Concilia,  vol  11,  p.  115;  Rot. 
Parl ,  vol  ii,  p  1296 

SJ  Cat  of  Letter  Books  of  the  City  of  London,  ed  R  R  Sharpe, 
vol  H,  pp  23-4,  24-5,  27,  28,  200/206-7,  261-2,  365,  Liber  Albus, 
bk  m,  pt  11,  pp  77,  315,  394-401,  683,  Selden  Soc,  Left  Jurisdiction 
in  the  City  of  Norwich,  p  V5 ,  Hist  MSS  Com  ,  MSS.  of  Marquis  of 
Lothian,  pp  26,  27 

82  Rot    Parl,  vol    11,  pp    332a,,  350& 

83  R   H   Morris,  Chester  in  the  Plantagenet  and  Tudor  Reigns.  1894 
(?),  p     190 

84  Early  Chancery  Proceedings,  Bdle    xi,  no    307 ;   Bdle    xxix,  nos 
193-5;  Bdle.  xxxi,  nos    96-100,  527,  Bdle    Ix,  no    20,  Bdle    Ixiv,  no. 
1080   See  also  Year  Books  and  Pica  Rolls  as  Sources  of  Historical  In- 
formation,  by  H    G    Richardson,  m  Tram    Royal  Historical  Society, 
4th  series,  vol    v,  1822,  pp    47-8 

85  Ed   Gibson,  Codex  Juris  Ecclesiastical  Angltcam,  2nd  ed  ,  1761,  p. 
1026 

86 15  Ed  III,  st  I,  c.  5;  3  Hen  VII,  c  5,  n  Hen  Vll,  c  8;  13 
Ehz  c  8,  21  Jac  I,  c.  17 

87  Cal  of  Early  Mayor's  Court  Rolls  of  City  of  London,  ed  A.  H. 
Thomas,  pp  1,  12,  28-9,  33-4,  44,  52,  88,  141,  156,  226,  235,  251  The 
cases  of  the  smiths  and  spurriers  occur  on  pp.  33-4  and  52.  In  the  fif- 
teenth century  a  gild  still  occasionally  tried  to  entorce  its  rules  by 
proceedings  m  an  ecclesiastical  court  (see  Wm  H  Hale,  A  Series  of 
Precedents  and  Proceedings  m  Criminal  Causes,  1847,  nos  xxxvi  and 
Ixviu,  where  persons  breaking  gild  rules  are  cited  before  the  Com- 
missary's court). 

*R  Canterbury  and  York  Soc  ,  Registrum  Thome  Spofford,  ed.  A. 
T  Bannister,  1919,  p.  52  (1424),  and  Surtees  Society,  vol  cxxxviii, 
The  Register  of  Thomas  of  Corbndge,  Lord  Archbishop  of  York,  ed 
Wm  Brown,  125,  vol  i,  pp  187-8  "6  kal  Mail,  1303  Wilton.'  Lit- 
tera  testimonials  super  purgacione  dommi  Johanms  de  Multhorp,  vi- 
caru  ecclesie  de  Carton',  de  usura  sibi  imposita  Universis  Chnsti  fide- 
libus,  ad  quos  prcsentes  httere  pervenerint,  pateat  per  easdem  quod, 
cum  dommus  Johannes  de  Multhorp',  vicanus  ecclesie  de  Carton*, 
nostre  diocesis,  coram  nobis  Thoma,  Dei  gracia,  etc.,  in  visitacione 
nostra  super  usura  fuisset  notatus,  videlicet,  quod  mutuavit  cuidam 
Jollano  de  Bnddale,  ut  dicebatur,  xxxiij  s  iiij  d  eo  pacto  quod  idem, 
vicanus  ab  eo  reciperet  per  x  annos  annis  smculis  x  s  pro  eisdem,  de 
quibus  eciam  dictum  fuit  quod  prefatus  Jollanus  dicto  vicario  pro 


248  NOTES 

octo  annis  ex  pacto  satisfecit  et  solvt  prediclo,  eundcm  vicanum  su- 
per hoc  vocan  fecimus  coram  nobis  et  ci  objecimus  suprachcta,  que 
ipse  inficians  constanctus  atque  negans  se  optull  in  forma  juris  super 
hiis  legitime  purgaturum  Nos  autem  eidem  vicano  purgacionem  suam 
cum  sua  sexta  manu  vicanorum  et  aliorum  presbiterorum  sui  ordims 
indiximus  faciendam,  quam  die  Venerib  proxima  ante  festum  aposto- 
lorum  Philippi  et  Jacobi  (April  26),  anno  gracie  m°ccc°  tercio,  ad 
hoc  sibi  prcnxo,  in  maneno  nostro  de  Wilton'  super  articulo  lecipimus 
supradicto,  idemque  vicanus  unacum  domirus  Johanne,  rectore  eccle<-ie 
B  M.  juxta  portam  castn  de  Eboraco,  Johanne  et  Johanne,  de  Whar 
rum  et  de  Wyverthorp'  ecclesiarum  vicarns  ac  Roberto,  Johanne, 
Alano,  Stepheno  et  Willelmo,  de  Nafferton',  Driffeld1,  Wetewang', 
Foston'  et  Wmtrmgham  ecclesiarum  presbitens  parochialibus  ndedig- 
nis,  de  memorato  articulo  legitime  se  purgavit ,  propter  quod  ipsum 
vicanum  sic  purgatum  pronunciamus  et  immunem  sentcnciahter  de~ 
claramus,  restituentes  eundem  ad  suam  pnstinam  bonam  famam  In 
cujus  rei  testimonium  sigillum  nostrum  presentibus  est  appensum  '' 

88  Early  Chancery  Proccedngs,  Bide  xvm,  no  137,  Bdle  xix,  no 
215?5,  Bdle  xxiv,  no  2^,  Bdle  xx\i,  no  U8  See  also  A  Abiam,  So- 
cial England  in  the  Fifteenth  Century,  1909,  pp  215-1 V  In  view  of 
tfeese  examples,  it  seems  probable  that  a  more  thorough  examination 
of  the  Early  Chancery  Proceedings  would  show  that,  even  in  the  fif- 
teenth century,  the  jurisdiction  of  the  ecclesiastical  courts  in  matters 
of  contract  and  usury  was  of  greater  practical  importance  than  has 
sometimes  been  supposed 

^Surtees  Soc ,  vol  Ixiv,  1874  (Acts  of  Chapter  of  the  Collegiate 
Church  of  Rjpon)  contains  more  than  100  cases  in  which  the  court 
deals  with  questions  of  contract,  debt,  etc  The  case  which  is  dismissed 
"propter  civihtatem  causae"  occurs  n  1532  (Surtees  oc  ,  vol  xxi,  18*5, 
Ecclesiastical  Proceedings  from  the  Courts  of  Durham,  p  40) 

91  Chetham  Soc  ,  vol  \liv,  1001,  Act  Book  of  the  Ecclesiastical  Court 
of  Whalley,  pp  15-16 

82  Surtees  Soc,  vol  Ixiv,  1775,  Acts  of  Chapter  of  the  Collegiate 
Church  of  Ripon,  p  26 

98  Hale,  op    cit    (note  87  above),  no    ccxxxvm 

94  See  Chap    III,  p    161 

95  For  parishes,  see  S   0   Addy,  Church  and  Manor,  1913,  chap   xv, 
where  numerous  examples  are  given   For  a  gild  which  appears  to  have 
acted  as  a  bank,  see  Hist    MSS    Com,  llth  Report,  1887,  Appx  ,  pt 
iii,  p    228  (MSS   of  the  Borough  of  Krng'\  Lynn],  and  for  other  ex- 
amples of  loans,  H   F   Westlake,  The  Parish  Gilds  of  Mediaeval  Eng- 
land, 191Q,  pp   61-1,  Records  of  the  City  of  Oxford,  ed   Wm    H   Tur- 
ner, 1880,  p   8,  Statutes  of  Lincoln  Cathedral,  ed    C    Wordsworth,  pt 
ii,  1807,  pp  616-17,  and  G   Unwm    The  Gilds  and  Companies  of  Lon- 
don, 1908,  p    121    For  a  hospital,  see  Hist    MSS    Com,  14th  Report, 
Appx,  pt    viu,  1805,  p    120   (MSS    of  tin    Corporation  of  Bury  St 
Edmunds],  where  20d   is  lent  (or  given)  to  a  poor  man  to  buy  seed 
for  his  land   A  statement  (made  half  a  century  after  the  Dissolution) 
as  to  loans  by  monasteries  is  quoted  by  F    A    Gasquet,  Henry  VUl 
and  the  English  Monasteries,  7th  ed  ,  1020,  p.  4=?3;  specfic  examples 
are  not  known  to  me. 

MW  H  Bliss,  Cal  of  Papal  Letters,  vol.  i.  pp   267-8 


NOTES   ON   CHAPTER  I  24$ 

"For  the  early  history  of  the  Monts  de  Piete  see  Halzapfel,  Dfa 
Anfange  der  Monies  Pietatis  (1903),  and  for  their  development  iftt 
the  Low  Countries,  A  Henne,  Histoire  du  Regne  de  Charles-quint  0Q 
Belgique,  1859,  vol.  v,  pp.  220-3.  For  proposals  to  establish  them  in 
England  see  SPD  Ehz  ,  vol  ex,  no  57  (printed  m  Tawney  and 
Power,  Tudor  Economic  Documents,  vol  in,  sect  m,  no  6)  and  my 
introduction  to  Thomas  Wilson's  Discourse  upon  Usury,  1925,  pp. 
125-7. 

HS  Camden  Soc  ,  A  Relation  of  the  Island  of  England  about  the  Year 
1500  (translated  from  the  Italian),  1847,  p.  23. 

"Lyndwood,  Provinciale,  sub.  tit  Usura,  and  Gibson,  Codex  /wr. 
Eccl  Angl ,  vol  11,  p  1020. 

100Pecock,  The  Repressor  of  over-much  blaming  of  the  Clergy,  pt. 
in,  chap  iv,  pp  296-7 .  "Also  Crist  sede  here  in  this  present  proces,  that 
'at  God'  it  is  possible  a  nche  man  to  entre  into  the  kingdom  of  heuen; 
that  is  to  seie,  with  grace  which  God  pro  frith  and  geueth  .  .  .  though 
he  abide  stille  riche,  and  though  withoute  such  grace  it  is  ouer  hard 
to  him  being  riche  to  entre  Wherfore  folewith  herof  openh,  that  it 
is  not  forbodun  of  God  eny  man  to  be  riche,  for  thanne  noon  sudi 
man  schulde  euere  entre  heuen.  .  .  And  if  it  be  not  forbode  eny  man 
to  be  nche,  certis  thanne  it  is  leeful  ynough  ech  man  to  be  riche;  in 
lasse  than  he  vowe  the  contrane  or  that  he  knowith  bi  assay  and 
experience  him  silf  so  miche  mdisposid  anentis  nchessis,  that  he 
schal  not  nowe  rcwle  him  silf  aright  anentis  tho  nchessis,  for  in  thilk 
caas  he  is  bonde  to  holde  him  silf  in  poverte "  The  embarrassing 
qualification  at  the  end — which  suggests  the  question,  who  then  dare 
be  rich? — is  the  more  striking  because  of  the  common-sense  ration- 
alism of  the  rest  of  the  passage 

101  Trithemius,  quoted  by  J   Janssen,  History  of  the  German  People 
at  the  close  of  the  Middle  Ages,  vol   ii,  1896,  p.  102. 

102  Cal.  of  Early  Mayor's  Court  Rolls  of  the  City  of  London,  ed.  A. 
H.  Thomas,  pp.  157-8. 

103  See  A.  Luchaire,  Social  France  at  the  time  of  Philip  Augusttu 
(translated  by  E.  B    Krehbiel),  pp   391-2,  where  an  eloquent  denun- 
ciation by  Jacques  de  Vitry  is  quoted 

104  Topographer  and  Genealogist,  vol.  i,  1846,  p.  35.  (The  writer  is 
a  surveyor,  one  Humberstone  ) 

105 See  eg.  Chaucer,  The  Persone's  Tale,  §§  64-6  The  parson  ex- 
presses the  orthodox  view  that  "the  condicioun  of  thraldom  and  the 
firste  cause  of  thraldom  is  for  sinne  "  But  he  insists  that  serfs  and 
lords  are  spiritually  equal  Thilke  that  thou  clepest  thy  thralles  been 
goddes  peple ;  for  humble  folk  been  Cristes  freendes  " 

10(!  Gratian,  Decretum,  pt.  ii,  causa  x,  Q  ii,  c  iii,  and  causa  xii,  Q, 
ii,  c.  xxxix 

107  Summa  Theol.,  la  2*,  Q.  xciv,  art  v,  §  3 

108  An  article  of  the  German  Peasants'  program  in  1525  declared: 
"For  men  to  hold  as  their  own  property        .  is  pitiable  enough,  con- 
sidering that  Christ  has  delivered  and  redeemed  us  all,  the  lowly  a* 
well  as  the  great,  without  exception,  by  the  shedding  of  His  precious 
blood.  Accordingly  it  is  consistent  with  Scripture  that  we  should  ta< 
free  "  (The  program  is  printed  in  J.  S.  Schapiro,  Social  Reform  <wwf ! 
the  Reformation,  1909,  pp.  137-42.)   The  rebels  under  Ket  prayed' 


NOTES 

"that  all  bondmen  may  be  made  free,  for  God  freed  them  all  with 
His  precious  blood-shedding"  (printed  m  Bland,  Brown,  and^  Tawney, 
English  Economic  History,  Select  Documents,  pt.  h,  sect,  i,  no.  8). 

CHAPTER  II 

I  A  Lecture  on  the  Studv  of  History,  delivered  at  Cambridge,  June 
11,  1895,  by  Lord  Acton,  p    9. 

2W  Sombart  (Der  moderne  Kapitahsmus,  1916,  vol  i,  pp  524-6) 
gives  fact  and  figures  See  also  J  Strieder,  Studien  zur  Geschvchte 
kapitahstischer  Organizations]  or  men,  1914,  kap  i,  ii 

3E  R  Daenell,  Die  Blutezett  der  Deutschen  Han\e,  1905,  Schanz, 
Englische  Handehpohtik  gegcn  das  Ende  des  Mittelalten,  vol  1 , 
N  S.  B  Gras,  The  Early  English  Customs  System,  1918,  pp  452-514 

4  E.g  ,  The  Fugger  News-Letters,  156S-1605,  ed.  V  von  Klarwill, 
trans  P  de  Chary,  1924 

5E  Alben,  Le  Relazwne  degli  Ambasciatori  Venett  al  Senato,  serie 
1,  vol  in,  1853,  p  357  (Relazwne  de  Filippo  11  Re  di  Spagna  da 
Michele  Soriano  nel  1559}  "Questi  sono  li  tesori  del  re  di  Spagna, 
queste  le  mimere,  qucste  Plndie  che  hanno  sostentato  1'imprese  dell' 
Imperatore  tanti  anni " 

6  The  best  contemporary  picture  of  the  trade  of  Antwerp  is  that  of 
L.  Guicciardim,  Descrittione  di  tutti  i  Paev  Basv   (1567),  of  which 
part  is  reprinted  in  a  French  translation  in  Tawney  and  Power,  Tudor 
Economic  Documents,  vol   in,  pp   149-173    The  best  modern  accounts 
of  Antwerp  are  given  by  Pirenne,  Histoire  de  Belgique,  vol    ii,  pp 
399-403,  and  vol  in,  pp   259-72 ,  Ehrenberg,  Das  Zeitalter  der  Fugger, 
vol.  ii,  pp  3-68;  and  J.  A   Gons,  Etude  sur  les  Colonies  Marchandes 
Meridionales  a  Anvcrs  de  14S8  a  1$67  (102*) 

7  The  Meutmgs  had  opened  a  branch  in  Antwerp  in  1479,  the  Hoch- 
stetters  m  1486,  the  Fuggers  in  1508,  the  Welsers  in  1509   (Pirenne, 
op  cit ,  vol  in,  p  261) 

8  Pirenne,  op    cit,  vol    iii,  pp    273-6 
n  Ehrenberg,  op  cit ,  vol  n,  pp   7-8 

10  A  short  account  of  international  financial  rein  lions  in  the  sixteenth 
century  will  be  found  in  my  introduction  to  Thomas  Wilson's  Dis- 
course upon  Usury,  1925,  pp  68-86 

II  Erasmus,  Adagia,  see  also  The  Complaint  of  Peace 

"For  the  Fuggers,  see  Ehrenberg,  op  cit ,  vol  i,  pp  85-186,  and 
for  the  other  German  fiims  mentioned,  ibid  ,  pp  187-260 

18  See  Gons,  op  cit.,  pp  510-45,  where  the  reply  of  the  Parsi  theo- 
logians is  printed  in  full;  and  Ehrenberg,  op  cit,  vol  n,  pp  18,  21. 
For  Bellarmin,  see  Gons,  op  cit ,  pp  551-2  A  curious  illustration  of 
the  manner  in  which  it  was  still  thought  necessary  in  the  later  six- 
teenth century,  and  in  Protestant  England,  to  reconcile  economic 
policy  with  canonist  doctrine,  will  be  found  m  S  P  D  Eliz .  vol 
Ixxv,  no.  54  (printed  in  Tawney  and  Power,  Tudor  Economic  Doc- 
uments, vol  iii,  pp  350-70)  The  writer,  who  is  urging  the  repeal  of 
the  Act  of  1552  forbidding  all  interest  whatever,  cites  Aquinas  and 
Hostiensis  to  prove  that  "trewe  and  unfayned  interest"  is  not  to  be 
condemned  as  usury. 

"Ashley,  Economic  History,  1893,  vol    i,  pt    ii,  pp    442-5 


NOTES   ON  CHAPTER  II  251 

"Bodin.  La  Response  de  Jean  Bodin  aux  Paradoxes  in  Malestroit 
touchant  I'enchenssement  de  toutes  choses  el  le  moyen  d'y  remedter. 

16  See    Max   Neumann,    Geschichte   des    Wuchers    in    Deutschland, 
1865,  pp  487  seqq 

17  Calvin's  views  will  be  found  in  his  Epistolce  et  Responsa,  1575, 
pp  3S5-7,  and  in  Sermon  xxvm  in  the  Opera 

18  Bucer,  De  Regno  Chnsti 

19  Third  Decade,  1st  and  2nd  Sermons,  in  The  Decades  of  Henry 
Bullmger  (Parker  Society),  vol   in,  1850 

20  Luther,  Kleiner  Sermon  vom  Wucher  (151Q)  in  Werke  (Weimalr 
ed  ),  vol    vi,  pp    1-8,  Grosser  Sermon  vom  Wucher  (1520),  in  ibid., 
pp   33-60,  Von  Kaufshandlung  and  Wucher  (1524),  in  ibid ,  vol    XV, 
pp   279-322,  An  die  Pfarrherrn  wider  den  Wucher  zu  predigen,  Ver* 
mahnung  (1^40),  in  ibid  ,  vol  li,  pp  32S-424 

ai  Hier  musste  man  wahrhch  auch  den  Fuckern  und  der  gentlichen 
GeselLschaft  emen  Zaum  im  Maul  legen"  (quoted  by  Ehrenberg,  op. 
at.,  vol  1,  p  117  n  ) 

"See  pp    114-15 

~lj  Luther,  Wider  die  taubenschen  und  mordenschen  Rotten  der 
Kauern  (1525),  in  Werke,  vol  xvm,  pp  357-61 

24Latimer,  Sermon*;,  Ponet,  An  Exhortation,  or  rather  a  Warning, 
to  the  Lords  and  Commons;  Crowley,  The  Way  to  Wealth,  and 
Epigrams  (in  Select  Works  of  Robert  Crowley,  ed  J  M  Cowper, 
EETS,  1872),  Lever,  Sermons,  1^0  (English  Reprints,  ed.  E. 
Arber,  1895);  Becon,  The  Jewel  of  Joy,  1553,  Sandys,  2nd,  10th, 
llth,  and  12th  of  Sermons  (Parker  Society,  1841),  Jewel,  Works, 
pt  iv,  pp  1293-8  (Parker  Society,  1850)  Citations  from  less  well- 
known  writers  and  preachers  will  be  found  in  J  O  W  Haweis, 
Sketches  of  the  Reformation,  1844 

2)Gairdner,  Letters  and  Papers  of  Henry  VIII,  vol    xvi,  no    357. 

20  Bossuet,  Traite  de  I'Uwie  For  an  account  of  his  views,  see 
Favre,  Le  pret  a  inter  et  dans  Vanaenne  France 

27  Brief  Survey  of  the  Growth  of  Usury  in  England  with  the  Mis- 
chiefs  attending  It,  1673 

28  For  an  account  of  these  changes  see  K    Lamprecht,  Zum  Ver- 
standniss  der  wirthschafthchen  und  sozialen  Wandlungen  m  Deutich- 
land  vom  14    zum  16   Jahrhundert,  in  the  Zeit^chnft  fur  Sozial-  und 
Wirthschuftsgcschichte,  Bd    i,  18Q3,  pp    101  seqq 

29  Lamprecht,  op    cit ,  and  J    S    Schapiro,  Social  Reform  and  the 
Reformation,  1909,  pp    40-73 

30  Schapiro,  op    cit ,  pp    20-39,  and  Stneder,  op.  cit    (see  note  2), 
pp    156-212 

31  For   the   so-called   Reformation   of  the   Emperor   Sigismund  see 
Chap    1,  note  24,  and  for  the  Peasants'  Articles,  ibid,  note  108 

152  For  Geiler  von  Kaiserberg  and  Hipler  see  Schapiro,  op  cit.,  pp. 
30,  126-31  For  Hutten  see  H  Wiskemann,  Dartstellung  der  in 
Deutschland  zur  Zeit  der  Reformation  herrschenden  Nationalokono- 
mischen  Ansichten,  1861,  pp.  13-24 

88  Quoted  W.  Raleigh,  The  English  Voyages  of  the  Sixteenth  Cen- 
tury,  1910,  p  28 

84Troeltsch,  Protestantism  and  Progress,  1912,  pp.  44-52. 


252  NOTES 

85Schapiro,  op   at ,  p    137 

88  See  citations  in  Wiskemann,  op  cit  ,  pp  47-8,  and,  for  a  discus- 
sion of  Luther's  social  theory,  Troeltsch,  Die  Soziallehren  der  Chnst- 
hchen  Kirchen,  1012,  pp  S4Q-93 

37  Luther,  An  den  chnsthchcn  Add  deutscher  Nation  (1520).  m 
Werke,  vol  vi,  pp  381  seqq 

M  Schapiro,  op    at  ,  p    139 

39  Luther,  Ermahnnng  zum  Fneden  auf  die  zwolf  Artikcl  der  Bauer- 
schaft  in  Schwaben   (1525),  in  Werke,  vol    xvm,  p    327 

40  Von  Kaufshandlung  und  Wucher,  in  ibid ,  vol    xv,  p    295 

41  An    den   christhchen  Adel,  in   ibid ,  vol    vi,   p    466    (quoted  by 
R    H    Murray,  Erasmus  and  Luther,  1020,  p    230) 

42  Von  Kaufshandlung  und  Wucher,  in  ibid ,  vol   \v,  pp   293-4,  312 

43  Concerning  Christian  Liberty,  in  Wace  and  Buchheim,  Luther's 
Primary  Works,  1806,  pp    256-7 

t4  Grosser  Sermon  vom  Wuchet,  in  Werkc,  vol    vi,  p   49 
4ft  See  note  73  on  Chapter  I 

40  Printed  in  Neumann,  Geschichte  des  Wucher  <>  in  Deutschland, 
Beilage  F,  pp  618-19 

47  Concerning   Christian  Liberty,  in  Wace  and  Buchheim,  op    cit., 
pp    258-0 

48  Von  Kaujshandlung  und  Wucher,  in  Werke,  vol    xv,  p    302 

49  Zwmgli,  Von  da  gotthchen  und  men^chhchen  Gricchtigkeit,  oder 
von  dem  gottlichen  Ge  seize  und  den  burgerhchen,  Ge^elzen,  printed 
in  R    Christoffel,  H    Zwmgli,  Leben  und  ausgewahlte  Schriften,  1857, 
pt    ii,  pp    3H   seqq    See  aKo  Wiskemann,  op    at,  pp    71-4 

60  "Quid  si  igitur  ex  nepociatione  plus  lucn  percipi  possit,  quam  ex 
fundi  cuiusvis  proventu?  Undc  vero  mercatons  lucrum  ^  Ex  ipmus 
inquies,  diligentia  et  mdu&tna"  (quoted  by  Troeltsch,  Die  Soziallehren 
der  Chntflichen  Kirche,  p  707) 

51  Bucer,  De  Regno  Chnsti 

B2  Ropjer  Fcnton,  A   Treatise  of  Usune,  1612,  p    61 

63  Calvin,  Institutes  of  the  Christian  Religion,  trans  by  J  Allen, 
1838,  vol  11,  p  147  (bk  m,  ch  xxm,  par  7) 

54  Ibid ,  vol  11,  pp  128-0  (bk  m,  ch  x\i,  par   7) 

55  Gerrard  Wmstanley,  A  New-Veer's  Gift    for  the  Parliament  and 
Armie,  1650  (Thomason  Tracts,  Brit    Mus ,  E    S87   [6],  p    42) 

*bThe  Works  of  William  Land,  DD  ,  ed  Wm  Scott,  vol  vi,  pt  i, 
1857,  p  21* 

57  De  Subventtone  Pauperum 

5S  "Quod  ad  maiores  natu  spectat,  a  nobis  quotannis  repetitur  in 
spectio  cumsque  famihac  Distiibuimus  inter  nos  urbis  reRiones,  ut 
ordme  singulas  decunas  executere  hteat  Adest  ministro  comes  unus 
ex  semoribus  lllic  novi  incola?  cxammantur  Qui  semel  recepti  sunt, 
omittuntur,  nisi  quod  requintur  sitne  domus  pacata  et  recte  com- 
posita,  num  htes  cum  vicinis,  num  qua  ebnetas,  num  pisri  smt  et 
ignari  ad  conciones  frequentendas"  (quoted  by  Wiskemann,  op  cit , 
p.  80  n  )  For  his  condemnation  of  indiscriminate  alms-giving,  see 
ibid,  p  79  n 

M  De  non  habendo  Pauperum  Delectu  (1523),  and  DC  Erogatione 
Eleemosynarum  (1524)  See  K  R  Ha^enbach,  Johann  Oekolampad 
und  Oswald  Myconius.  die  Reformatoren  Baseh,  1859.  D.  46. 


NOTES   ON   CHAPTER  IT  253 

60  Carl  Pestalozzi,  Hennch  Bullmger,  Leben  und  ausgewahlte 
Schriften,  1858,  pp  50-1,  122-5,  340-2 

01  Wiskemann,  op.  at  ,  pp    70-4 

w  Quoted  by  Preserved  Smith,  The  Age  of  the  Reformation,  1921, 
p  174 

fl<  Calvin,  Jnst ,  bk    iv,  ch    xii,  par    1 

M  Printed  in  Paul  Henry,  Das  Leben  Johann  Calvins,  vol.  ii,  1838, 
Appx,  pp  26-41. 

6r>  R  Chnstoffel,  Zwmgli,  or  the  Rise  of  the  Reformation  in  Switz- 
erland, trans  by  John  Cochran,  1858,  pp  159-60 

''"Printed  m  Paul  Henrv,  op    cit ,  vol    n,  Appx,  pp    23-5. 

07  E  Choisy,  L'Etat  Chretien  Calvmiste  a  Geneve  au  temps  de 
Theodore  de  Beze,  1902,  p  145  I  should  like  to  make  acknowledg- 
ments to  this  excellent  book  for  most  of  the  matter  contained  in  the 
following  paragraphs 

tiH  Paul  Henry,  op  cit ,  pp  70-5  Other  examples  arc  given  by  Pre- 
served Smith,  op  cit ,  pp  170-4,  and  by  F  W  Kampschulte,  Johann 
Calvin,  seme  Kirche  und  sein  Staat  in  Gcnf,  I860  Statistical  esti- 
mates of  the  bloodthirstmess  of  Calvin's  regime  vary,  Smith  (p  171) 
states  that  in  Geneva,  a  town  of  16,000  inhabitants,  58  persons  were 
executed  and  76  banished  in  the  years  1542-6 

""  Knox,  quoted  by  Preserved  Smith,  op    cit ,  p    174 

70  Calvin,  Jnst  ,  bk    in,  ch    vn,  par    5 

71  Choisy,  op    cit  ,  pp    442-3 
''"Ibid,  pp     tf-W 

13  Ibid  ,  pp    180,   117-19 
74  Ibid ,  pp    035,  165-7 
7r  Ibid  ,  pp    110-21 
"'*  Ibid,  pp    180-04 

77  Paul  Henry,  op    cit ,  vol    ii,  p    70  n 

78  See  the  description  of  the  Church  given  in  Calvin,  Inst.,  bk.  iv, 
ch    i,  par    4    "Quia  nunc  dc  ecclesia  visibili  dissererc  propositum  est 
discamus  vel  matns  elogio,  quam  utilis  sit  nobis  ems  cogmtio,  immo 
necessana,    quando    non    alms   est   in    vitam    ingressus    nisi   nos   ipsa 
concipiat  m  utero,   nisi   panat,   nisi   nos   alat   STUS   uberibus,   denique 
sub   custodia   ct   gubernatione   sua   nos   tueatur,   donee    excuti   carne 
mortali,  similes  enmus  angehs    Neque  enim  prititur  nostra  infirmitas 
a  schola  nos  dimitti,  donee  toto  vitae  cursu  discipuh  fuenmus    Adde 
quod   extra   ems   gremium   nulla   est   esperanda   peccatorum    remissio 
nee  ulla  salus  " 

71)  John  Quick,  Synodicon  m  Gallm  Reformata  Or  the  Arts,  Deci- 
sions, Dectees  and  Canons  of  those  famous  National  Councils  of  the 
Reformed  Churches  in  France,  1602,  vol  i,  p  90 

80  Ibid,  vol    i,  p    0  (pirates  and  fraudulent  tiadesmen),  pp    25,34, 
38,  70,  140  (interest  and  usury),  p    70  (false  merchandise  and  selling 
of  stretched  cloth),  p  o  (reasonable  profits),  pp    162,  204  (investment 
of  money  for  the  benefit  of  the  poor),  pp    104,  213   (lotteries). 

81  The'  Buke  of  Discipline,  in  Works  of  John  Knox,  ed    D.  Laing, 
vol    ii,  1848,  p    227 

82  Scottish    History   Soc ,   St    Andrews   Kirk   Session   Register,  ed. 
D    H    Fleming,  1889-90,  vol    i,  p    309,  vol    ii,  p    822 

83  W.  B    Weeden,  Economic  and  Social  History  of  New  England, 


254  NOTES 

1890,  vol  i,  p.  11    The  words  are  Governor  Bradford's. 

84  Winthrop's  Journal  "Hittory  of  New  England''  1630-49,  ed.  J.  K. 
Hosmer,  1908,  vol  i,  pp  134,  325;  vol  ii,  p.  20 

MWeeden,  op   cit ,  vol   i,  pp    125,  58 

86  Wmthrop,  op.  cit  ,  vol    ii,  p    20. 

87  J.  A    Doyle,  The  English  in  America,  vol    ii,   1887,  p.  57;  the 
price  of  cattle  "must  not  be  judged  by  urgent  necessity,  but  by  rea- 
sonable profit." 

88  Roger  Williams,  The  Bloudy  Tenent  of  Persecution,  1644,  chap, 
Iv, 

89  Wmthrop,  op  ctt.,  vol  i,  pp  315-18   A  similar  set  of  rules  as  to 
the  conduct  of  the  Christian  in  trade  are  given  by  Bunyan  in  The  Life 
end  Death  oj  Mr  Badman,  1905  ed  ,  pp   118-22 

80 1  owe  this  phrase  to  the  excellent  book  of  J.  T.  Adams,  The 
Founding  of  New  England 

CHAPTER  III 

1  J.  Rossus,  Historia  Regum  Anglioe  (ed  T  Hearne). 

*4  Hen.  VII,  c.  19;  6  Hen  VIII,  c  5;  7  Hen  VIII,  c.  1;  25 
Hen  VIII,  c.  13  For  the  Commission  of  1517  see  Leadam,  The 
Domesday  of  Enclosures 

8  For  examples  see  J.  S  Schapiro,  Social  Reform  and  the  Refor- 
mation, pp  60-1,  65,  67,  70-1 

4  More,  Utopia,  p    32   (Pitt  Press  ed ,  1879)  "Noblemen  and  gen- 
tlemen, yea  and  certeyne  abbottes,  holy  men  no  doubt  .  .  .  leave  no 
grounde  for  tillage,  thei  enclose  al  into  pastures "  For  a   case   of 
claiming  a  bondman  see  Selden  Society,  vol.  xvi,  1903,  Select  Cases 
in  the  Court   of  Star  Chamber,  pp.  cxxhi-cxxix,   118-29    (Carter  v. 
the  Abbott  of  Malmesbury) ;  for  conversion  of  copyholds  to  tenancies 
at  will,  Selden  Society,  vol    xii,  1898,  Select  Case\  in  the  Court  of 
Requests,  pp   lix-lxv,  64-101  (Kent  and  other  inhabitants  of  Abbot's 
Ripton  v.  St.  John;   the  change  was  alleged  to  have  been  made  m 
1471). 

5  A.   Savine,  English  Monasteries   on   the  Eve   of   the  Dissolution 
(Oxford   Studies   in   Social  and   Legal  History,   ed    P    Vmogradoff, 
vol.  i,  1909,  p.  100),  estimates  the  net  temporal  income  of  English 
monasteries  in  1535  at  £100,736,  and  the  net  income  from  all  sources 
at  £136,361.  These  figures  require  to  be  multiplied  by  at  least  12  to 
convert  them  into  terms  of  modern  money   An  estimate  of  the  capital 
value  which  they  represent  can  only  be  a  guess,  but  it  can  hardly 
have  been  less  (in  terms  of  modern  money)  than  £20,000,000 

*For  the  status  and  payments  of  grantees,  see  the  figures  of  Savine, 
printed  in  H.  A.  L.  Fisher,  The  Political  History  of  England,  1485- 
1547,  Appx.  ii-  the  low  price  paid  by  peers  is  particularly  striking 
The  best  study  is  that  of  S  B  Liljegren,  The  Fall  oj  the  Monasteries 
and  the  Social  Changes  in  England  leading  up  to  the  Great  Revolution 
(1924),  which  shows  in  detail  (pp.  18-25)  the  activities  of  speculators. 

*  Star  Chamber  Proc.,  Hen.  VIII,  vol.  vi,  no.  181,  printed  in  Taw- 
ney  and  Power,  Tudor  Economic  Documentsf  vol.  i,  pp.  19-29 


NOTES  ON  CHAPTER  III  255 

"Selden  Society,  Select  Cases  in  the  Court  of  Requests,  pp.  Iviii- 
Ixix,  198-200. 

"Quoted  by  F  A  Gasquet,  Henry  the  Eighth  and  the  English 
Monasteries,  1020,  pp  227-8 

10  See,  e  g ,  The  Obedience  of  a  Christian  Man  (in  Tyndale's  Doc- 
trinal Treatises,  Parker  Society,  1848),  p  231,  where  the  treatment 
of  the  poor  by  the  early  Church  is  cited  as  an  example,  and  Policies 
to  reduce  this  Realme  of  Englande  unto  a  Prosperous  Wealthe  and 
Estate,  1540  (printed  m  Tdwney  and  Power,  Tudor  Economic  Doc- 
uments, vol  m,  pp  311-4?)  "Like  as  we  suffered  our  selfes  to  be 
ignorant  of  the  trewe  worshipping  of  God,  even  so  God  kepte  from 
us  the  right  knowledge  how  to  reforme  those  inconveniences  which 
we  did  see  before  our  eyes  to  tende  unto  the  utter  Desolation  of  the 
Realme  But  now  that  the  trew  worshipping  of  Code  is  so 

purely  and  sincerely  sett  foithe,  it  is  likewise  to  be  trusted  that  God 
will  use  the  kinges  majestie  and  your  grace  to  be  also  his  min- 
istres  m  plucking  up  by  the  roots  all  the  cawses  and  occasions  of  this 
foresaid  Decaye  and  Desolation  " 

31  Bucer,  De  Regno  Chnsti 

}"  A  F  Leach,  The  Schools  of  Mediaeval  England,  1015,  p  331  He 
goes  on  'The  contrasts  between  one  grammar  school  to  every  5,625 
people,  and  that  presented  by  the  Schools  Inquiry  Report  m  1864  of 
one  to  every  23,750  people  is  not  to  the  disadvantage  of  our 

pre-Reformalion  ancestors  "  For  details  of  the  Edwardian  spoliation, 
see  the  same  author's  English  Schools  at  the  Reformation,  1546-8 
(1806) 

13  See  Acts  of  the  Privy  Council,  vol    ii,  pp.  103-5   (1548);  in  re- 
sponse to  protests  from  the  members  for  Lynn  and  Coventry,  the  gild 
lands  of  those  cities  are  regranted  to  them 

14  Crowley,  The  Way  to  Wealth,  in  Select  Works  of  Robert  Crow- 
ley,  ed    J    M    Cowper  (Early  English  Text  Society,  1872,  pp    129- 
150) 

ir' Crowley,  op  cit ,  and  Epigrams  (in  ibid,  pp  1-51) 
1('Becon,  The  Jewel  of  Joy,  1553  "They  abhore  the  names  of 
Monkes,  Friers,  Chanons,  Nonnes,  etc ,  by  their  goodes  they  gredely 
gripe  And  yet  where  the  cloysters  kept  hospitality,  let  out  their 
fermes  at  a  reasonable  price,  nonshed  scholes,  brought  up  youth  in 
good  letters,  they  do  none  of  all  these  thynges  " 

17  Thomas  Lever,  Sermons,  1550   (English  Reprints,  ed    E.  Arber, 
1805),  p    32    The  same  charge  is  repeated  in  subsequent  sermons 

18  F    W    Russell,  Kelt's   Rebellion   in  Norfolk,    1859,   p     202     For 
Somerset's  policy  and  the  revolt  of  the  gentry  against  it,  see  Tawney, 
The  Agrarian  Problem  m  the  Sixteenth   Century,  pp    365-70 

1MLatimer,  Seven  Sermons  before  Edward  VI  (English  Reprints, 
ed  E  Arber,  1805),  pp  4-6 

20  Pleasure  and  Pain,  in  Select  Works  of  Robert  Crowley ,  ed  J.  M. 
Cowper,  p  116 

"  The  way  to  Wealth,  in  ibid  ,  p  132 

22  Lever,  op   cit ,  p    130 

23  A  Prayer  for  Landlords,  from  A  Book  of  Private  Praver  set  forth 
by  Order  of  King  Edward  VI 

24  Bacon,  Of  the  True  Greatness  of  the  Kingdom  of  Britain. 


2S6  NOTES 

96  For  a  discussion  of  the  problem  of  credit  as  it  affected  the  peas- 
ant and  small  master,  see  my  introduction  to  Wilson's  Discourse  Upon 
Usury,  1Q2S,  pp  17-30 

26  See  note  71  on  Chapter  I 

"D'Ewes,  Journals,  1682,  p    173. 

28  Calendar  SP  D    Ehz  ,  vol    cclxxxvi,  nos    19,  20 

29  For  examples  see  S   0   Addy,  Church  and  Manor,  1913,  chap   xv. 
The  best  account  of  parish  business  and  organization  is  given  by  S   L 
Ware,  The  Elizabethan  Parish  in  its  Ecclesiastical  and  Financial  As- 
pects, 1908 

90  Lever,  op.  cit.,  p  130  See  also  Harrison,  Thv  Description  of 
Bntamc,  15S7  cd  ,  bk  n,  chap  xviu 

81  A  Godhe  Treatise  concerning  the  Lawful  Use  of  Riches,  a  trans- 
lation by  Thos  Rogers  from  the  Latin  of  Nicholas  Heming,  1578, 
p.  8 

32  Sandys,  2nd,  10th,  llth,  and  12th  of  Sermons  (Parker  Society, 
1841),  Jewel,  Works,  pt  iv,  pp  1293-8  (Parker  Society,  1850)  ,  Thos 
Wilson,  A  Discourse  upon  Usury,  1572,  Miles  Mosse,  The  Arraign- 
ment and  Conviction  oj  Usune,  1W,  John  Blaxton,  The  English 
Usurer,  or  Usury  Condemned  by  the  Most  Learned  and  Famous 
Divines  of  the  Church  of  England,  1634 

83  Heming,  op    cit ,  pp    16-17. 

"Roger  Fenton,  A    Treatise  of  Usune,  1612,  p    59. 

85  Wilson,  op    cit  ,  1925,  ed    p    281 

86  Miles  Mosse,  op    cit. 

87  SP.D.  Ehz,  vol    Ixxv,  no    54    (Printed  in  Tawney  and  Power, 
Tudor  Economic  Documents,  vol    hi,  pp    350-70) 

"Heming,  op    cit,  p    11 

89  Maitland,  English  Law  and  the  Renaissance,  1901 

40  Quoted  by  Maitland,  op   cit ,  pp   49-50 

41  Wilson,  op   cit 

42  Jeremy  Taylor,  Ductor  Dubitantium,  1660,  bk  iii,  ch   iii,  par  30 
48  Mosse,  op    cit.,  Dedication,  p    6 

44  E.  Cardwell,  Synodalla,  1842,  p  436 

"Cardwell,  The  Reformation  of  the  Ecclesiastical  Laws,  1850,  pp. 
206,  323 

46  The  Remains  of  Archbishop  Gnndal,  ed   Wm   Nicholson  (Parker 
Soc,  1843),  p    143 

47  See,  e  g ,  W   P    M    Kennedy,  Elizabethan  Episcopal  Administra- 
tion,  1924,   vol    iii,   p     180    (Archdeacon    Mullms'   Articles   for    the 
Archdeaconry  of  London  (1585)     "Item,  whether  you  do  know  that 
within  your  parish  there  is  (or  are)  any  person  or  persons  notoriously 
known  or  suspected  by  probable  tokens  or  common  fame  to  be  an 
usurer;  or  doth  offend  by  any  colour  or  means  directly  or  indirectly 
in  the  same"),  and  pp.  184,  233;  Wilkins,  Concilia,  vol    iv,  pp    319, 
337,  416. 

48  Cardwell,  Synodalia,  vol   i,  pp.  144,  308 ,  Wilkins,  Concilia,  vol. 
iv,  p.  509. 

49  Ware,  op   cit.  (see  note  29  above),  quotes  several  examples.  See 
also  ArchfKologia  Cantiana,  vol.  xxv,  1902,  pp.  27,  48  (Visitations  of 
the  Archdeacon  of  Canterbury). 


NOTES  ON  CHAPTER  III  257 

5"  Hist  MSS  Com,  13th  Report,  1892,  Appx ,  pt  iv,  pp  333-4 
(M  S  S  of  the  Borough  of  Hereford} 

0]  W.  H  Hale,  A  Scries  of  Precedents  and  Proceedings  in  Criminal 
Causes,  1847,  p  166 

32  Yorkshire  Arth    Journal,  vol    xvm,  1895,  p    331 

63  Commi^ary  of  London  Correction  Books,  1618-1625  (H  184,  pp. 
164,  1«2)  I  am  indebted  to  Mr  Fmcham  of  Somerset  House  (where 
the  books  are  kept)  for  kindly  calling  my  attention  to  these  cases. 
The  shorter  of  them  (p  192)  runs  as  follows 

Sancti  Botolphi  ,  Detected  for  an  usurer  that  takcth  above  the 
extra  Aldersgate  1  rate  of  x11  in  the  100lJ  and  above  the  rate  of  2i. 
Thomas  Witham  '  m  the  pound  for  money  by  him  lent  for  a  yeare, 

at  the  signe  of      f  or  more  than  after  that  rate  for  a  lesse  tyme 

the   Unicorne       *  ex  fama  prout  in  rotula   Quo  die  comparuit,  etc. 

9wo  Man  1620  coram  domino  official!  principal!  etc  et  in  eius 
camera  etc  comparuit  dictus  Witham  et  ei  objecto  ut  supra  allegavit 
that  he  is  seldom  at  home  himselfe  but  leaves  his  man  to  deale  in  the 
business  of  his  shop,  and  yf  any  fault  be  committed  he  saith  the  fault 
is  in  his  man  and  not  in  himselfe,  and  he  saycth  he  will  give  charge 
and  take  care  that  no  oppression  shall  be  made  nor  offence  committed 
this  way  hereafter,  humbly  praying  the  judge  for  favour  to  be  dis- 
missed, unde  clommus  monuit  eum  that  thereafter  neither  by  himselfe 
nor  his  servant  he  offende  in  the  lyke  nor  suffer  any  such  oppression 
to  be  committed,  et  cum  hac  momtione  eum  dimisit 

^SPD    Ehz,  vol    Ixxv,  no    S4 

56  For  an  account  of  these  expedients  see  my  introduction  to  Wil- 
son's Discourse  upon  Usury,  1925,  pp  123-8 

5l>  Richard  Hooker,  The  Law*  of  Ecclesiastical  Policy,  bk  vm,  chap, 
i,  par  5 

07  Acts  of  the  Privy  Council,  vol    xxvn,   1W,  p    129 

'*The  Stiff  key  Papers  (ed  H  W  Saunders,  Roval  Historical 
Society,  Camden  Third  Series,  vol  xxvi,  1915),  p  140 

511  Quoted  by  E  M  Leonard,  The  Early  History  of  English  Poor 
Rehef,  1900,  p  148 

60  For  an  account  of  the  treatment  of  exchange  business  under 
Elizabeth,  see  Wilson,  op  at  ,  Introduction,  pp  146-54 

(>1  Foi  references  sec  ibid  ,  pp  164- S,  and  Les  Repoites  del  Cases 
in  Camera  Stellata,  15Q3-160Q,  ed  W  P  Baildon,  1894,  pp  235-7. 
The  Utter  book  contain^  several  instances  of  intervention  by  the 
Star  Chamber  in  cases  of  engrossing  of  corn  (pp  71,  76-7,  78-9,  91) 
and  of  enclosure  and  depopulation  (pp  49-52,  164-5,  192-3,  247, 
346-7) 

<!2  A  Discourse  of  the  Common  Weal  of  this  Realm  of  England,  ed. 
E  Lamond,  1893,  p  14 

*"The  Work*,  of  William  Laud,  D  D  ,  ed  Wm  Scott, vol  i,1847,p  6. 

«>lbid,  p    64 

("lbid,  pp    89,  138 

Mlbid,    p     167 

"Ibid,   pp    28-29 

68  Conner,  Common  Land  and  Enclosure,  1912,  pp  166-7  For 
the  activity  of  the  Government  from  1629  to  1640,  see  Tawney,  The 


258  NOTES 

Agrarian  Problem  in  the  Sixteenth  Century,  pp  376,  301,  and  E  M. 
Leonard,  The  Inclosnre  of  Common  Fields  in  the  Seventeenth  Cen- 
tury, in  Trans  Royal  Htrt  Soc ,  N  S  ,  vol  MX,  pp  101  seqq 

**  Letter  to  Dr  'Gilbert  Sheldon  Warden  of  All  Souls  (in  Laud's 
Works,  vol  vi,  pt  n,  p  520)  "One  thing  more  T  must  tell  you, 
that,  though  I  did  vou  this  favour,  to  make  stay  of  the  hearing  till 
your  return,  yet  for  the  business  itself,  I  can  show  you  none ,  partly 
because  I  am  a  great  hater  of  depopulations  in  any  kind,  as  being 
one  of  the  greatest  mischiefs  in  this  kingdom,  and  of  very  ill  example 
from  a  college,  or  college  tenant",  Clarendon,  History  of  the  Re- 
bellion, bk  i,  par  204 

70  5?  D  Chas  I,  vol  ccccxcix,  no  10  (printed  in  Tawney,  The 
Agrarian  Problem  in  the  Sixteenth  Century,  pp  420-1) ,  and  Lords' 
Journals,  vol  vi,  p  4686  (March  13,  1643-4),  Articles  against  Laud 
"Then  Mr  Talbot  upon  oath  deposed  how  the  Archbishop  did  oppose 
the  law  in  the  business  of  mclosures  and  depopulations,  how,  when 
the  law  was  desired  to  be  pleaded  for  the  right  of  land,  he  bid  them 
'Go  plead  law  in  inferior  Courts,  they  should  not  plead  it  before 
him',  and  that  the  Archbishop  did  fine  him  for  that  business  two 
hundred  pounds  for  using  the  property  of  his  freehold,  and  would 
not  suffer  the  law  to  be  pleaded  " 

"Leonard,  The  Early  History  of  English  Pooi  Relief,  pp  150-64; 
Unwin,  Industrial  Organization  in  the  Sixteenth  and  Seventeenth 
Centuries,  1904,  pp  142-7 

74  R  R   Reid,  The  Km%'\  Council  in  the  North,  1921,  pp   412,  413  n 

T8  Camden  Soc  ,  N  S  ,  vol  xxxix,  1886,  Cases  tn  the  Courts  of  Star 
Chamber  and  Hiqh  Commission,  ed  S  R  Gardiner,  p  46  For  an- 
other case  of  engrossing  of  corn,  see  ibid ,  pp  82-9 

"Tawney,  The  Assessment  of  Wages  in  England  by  the  Justices  of 
the  Peace,  in  Vierteljahischiift  fur  Sozial-  und  Wirthschaftsgeschtchte, 
Bd  xi,  1913,  pp  551-4,  Leonard,  op  at,  p  157 

78  The  Works  of  William  Laud,  ed  Wm  Scott,  vol  vi,  18^7,  pt  i, 
p.  191  (Answer  to  Lord  Save  and  Sele's  speech  upon  the  Bill  about 
Bishops'  Powers  in  Civil  Affairs  and  Courts  of  Judicature  ) 

™Ibid,  vol    i,  pp    5-6 

"Harrington,  Works,  1700  ed  ,  pp  69  (Oceana)  and  388-9  (The 
Art  of  Law- giving) 

78  G.  Malynes,  Lex  Mercatoria,  1622  The  same  simile  had  been 
used  much  earlier  in  A  Discourse  of  the  Common  Weal  of  this  Realm 
of  England,  ed  E.  Lamond,  p  98 

TeD'Ewes,  Journals,  p    674,  and  39  Ehz  ,  c    2 

80  For  criticisms  of  price  control  see  Tawney  and  Power,  Tudor 
Economic  Documents,  vol  in,  pp  339-41,  and  vol.  li,  p  188,  and 
Stiffkey  Papers  (see  note  58  above),  pp  130-40 

81 H  Ellis,  Original  Letters,  2nd  series,  vol  ii,  1827,  letter  clxxxn, 
and  J.  W  Burgon,  The  Life  and  Times  of  Sir  Thomas  Gresham, 
1839,  vol  ii,  p  343 

"Wilson,  op   cit    (see  note  55  above),  p    249. 

M  Commons'  Journals,  May  21,  1604,  vol.  i,  p    218 

84 13  Eliz.,  c.  8,  repealing  5  and  6  Ed  VI,  c.  20;  D'Ewes,  Journals, 
pp.  171-4. 


NOTES  ON  CHAPTER  IV  2S9 

85  Owen  and  Blakeway,  Historv  of  Shrewsbury,  1825,  vol.  ii,  pp, 
364n  ,412 

86  Hist   MSS.  Com  ,  Report  on  MSS   in  various  Collections,  vol.  i, 
1901,  p   46  (MSS   of  Corporation  of  Burford) 

ST  Wilson,   op    cit     (see   note   55    above),   p    233 

88  Coke,  Institutes,  pt  11,  17Q7,  pp  001  seqq  (Certain  articles  oj 
abuses  which  are  desiied  to  be  reformed  in  granting  oj  prohibitions, 
exhibited  by  Richard  Bancroft,  Archbishop  of  Canterbury.) 

s"  Thomas  Ridley,  A  View  of  the  Civile  and  Ecclesiastical  Law, 
and  when  in  the  Practice  oj  them  zs  t>treitened  and  may  be  relieved 
wiihm  this  Land,  1607,  Dedication,  p  3 

"°W  Hunlley,  A  Breviate  of  the  Prelates'  intolerable  Usurpation, 
16n,  pp  183-4  The  case  referred  to  is  that  of  Hmde,  alleged  to  have 
been  heard  Mich  18  and  1Q  Eh/  For  the  controversy  over  prohibi- 
tions, see  R  G  Usher,  The  Rne  and  ball  oj  the  High  Commission, 
1013,  pp  180  seqq 

91D'Ewes,  Journals,   pp     171,    173 

"See  e  g  ,  Surtees  Society,  vol  xxxiv,  18S8,  The  Acts  oj  the  High 
Commission  Court  within  the  Diocese  oj  Durham,  Preface,  which 
shows  that  between  1626  and  1630  cases  of  contempt  of  the  ordinary 
ecclesiastical  jurisdiction  ran  into  hundreds 

"JPenn,  No  Cross,  No  Crown,  pt   i,  ch   xu,  par   8 

M  Sanderson,  De  Obligatwne  Conscientice,  1666,  Taylor,  The  Rule 
and  Exercises  of  Holy  Living,  1650,  chap  m,  sect  iii  (Of  Negotiation 
or  Civil  Contracts,  Rules  and  Measures  of  Justice  m  Bargaining). 

05Mandeville,  The  Fable  of  the  Bees,  ed  F  B  Kaye,  1924,  pp.  193, 
194  Similar  sentiments  with  regard  to  the  necessity  of  poverty  were 
expressed  later  by  the  Rev  J  Townsend,  in  his  Dissertation  on  the 
Poor  Laws  (1785),  and  by  Patrick  Colquhoun  m  his  Treatise  on  the 
Wealth  and  Resources  of  the  Rritish  Empire  (1814)  Like  Mandeville, 
both  these  writers  argue  that  poverty  is  essential  to  the  prosperity, 
and,  indeed,  to  the  very  existence  of  civilization  For  a  full  collection 
of  citations  to  the  same  effect  from  eighteenth-century  writers,  see 
E  E  Furni^s,  The  Position  oj  the  Laborer  in  a  System  of  National- 
ism, 1Q20,  chaps  iv-vi 

B($  The  Whole  Duty  of  Man,  laid  down  in  a  plain  and  familiar  Way 
for  the  Use  of  All,  1658 

CHAPTER  IV 

1  Tucker,  A  Brief  Essay  on  the  Advantages  and  Disadvantages 
which  respectively  attend  France  and  Great  Britain  with  regard  to 
Trade,  1750,  p  33  The  best  account  of  Tucker,  most  of  whose  works 
are  scarce,  is  given  by  W  E  Clark,  Josiah  Tucker,  Economist  (Stud- 
ies in  History,  Economics  and  Public  Law,  Columbia  University, 
vol  xix,  1903-5). 

3  Rehquice  Baxterianae:  or  Mr  Richard  Baxter's  Narrative  of  the 
most  memorable  Passages  of  his  Life  and  Times,  1696,  p.  5. 

*  Bunyan,  The  Pilgrim's  Progress 

*  The  Life  of  the  Duke  of  Newcastle,  by  Margaret,  Duchess  of  New* 
castle  (Everyman  ed.,  1915,  p  153) 

B  Baxter,  op.  at.,  p.  31. 


260  NOTES 

8  Bunyan,  The  Pilgrim's  Progress. 

*  Baxter,  op    at ,  p    89 

8  Thomas  Fuller,  The  Holy  and  Profane  States,  1884  ed  ,  p    122 

"Quoted  S    Seyer,  Memoirs  of  Bristol,  vol   li,  1823,  p   314 

10  R.  G  Usher,  The  Reconstruction  oj  the  English  Church,  vol  i, 
1910,  pp  249-50 

"Baxter,  op    cit ,  p    30 

M  An  orderly  and  plaine  Narration  of  the  Beginnings  and  Causes 
of  this  Warre,  1644,  p  4  (Brit  Mus  Thomason  Tiacts,  E  54  HI) 
I  owe  this  reference  to  the  kindness  of  Father  Paschal  Larkin 

"Clarendon,  History  of  the  Rebellion,  bk    vi,  par    271. 

"Parker,  Discourse  of  Ecclesiastical  Pohtie,  1670,  Preface,  p   xxxix 

"The  Life  of  Edward,  Earl  of  Clarendon,  written  by  himself,  1827 
ed  ,  vol  in,  p  101 

18  D  C  A  Agnew,  Protestant  Enles  from  Ftance,  1886,  vol  i,  pp 
20-1  In  1640  the  Root  and  Branch  Petition  included,  among  the  evils 
due  to  the  Bishops,  "the  discouragement  and  destruction  oi  all  good 
subjects,  of  whom  are  multitudes,  both  clothiers,  merchants  and 
others,  who,  being  deprived  of  their  ministers,  and  overburthcned 
with  these  pressures,  have  departed  the  kingdom  to  Holland  and 
other  parts,  and  have  drawn  with  them  a  gieat  manufacture  of 
cloth  and  trading  out  of  the  land  into  other  plates  where  they  re- 
side, whereby  wool,  the  great  staple  of  the  kingdom,  is  become  of 
small  value,  and  vends  not,  trading  is  decayed,  many  poor  people 
want  work,  seamen  lose  employment,  and  the  whole  land  is  much 
impoverished"  (S  R  Gardiner,  Constitutional  Documents  of  the 
Puritan  Revolution,  1628-60  |188Q|,  p  7*)  For  instances  of  the  com- 
paratively liberal  treatment  of  alien  immigrants  under  Elizabeth,  see 
Tawney  and  Power,  Tudor  Economic  Documents,  vol  i,  section  vi, 
nos  3,  4,  11  (2),  15,  and  Cunningham,  Growth  oj  English  Industry 
and  Commerce,  Modern  Times,  1921,  pt  i,  pp  7°-84 

™  Toryism  and  Trade  can  never  agree,  1713,  p  12  The  tract  is 
wrongly  ascribed  to  Davenant  by  H  Levy,  Economic  Liberalism, 
1913,  p  12. 

18  See,  e   g  ,  G    Martin,  La  Grande  Industrie  sous  le  regne  de  Louis 
XIV,  1899,  chap    xvu,  where  the  reports  of  several  mtendants  are 
quoted,    and   Levacseur,  Hist  one  du   commerce  dc   la   Fiance,   1911, 
vol  i,  p  421 

19  A  Letter  from  a  Gentleman  in  the  City  to  a  Gentleman  in  the> 
Country  about  the  Odiousness  of  Persecution,   1677,  p    20 

20  Sir  Wm    Temple,  Observations  upon  the  United  Provinces  oj  the 
Netherlands,  chap    v,  vi 

21  The  True  Interest  and  Political  Maxims  of  the  Republick  of  Hol- 
land and  West-Fnesland,  1702,  pt    i,  chap    xiv 

2"  Petty,  Political  Arithmetic,  1690,  pp    25-6 

23  The  Present  Interest  of  England  stated,  by  a  Lover  of  his  King 
and  Country,  1671  I  am  indebted  to  Mr  A  P  Wadsworth  for  calling 
my  attention  to  the  passage  quoted  in  the  text  The  same  point  is  put 
more  specifically  by  Lawrence  Braddon  "The  superstition  of  their 
religion  obligeth  France  to  keep  (at  least)  fifty  Holy  days  more  than 
we  are  obliged  to  keep;  and  every  such  day  wherein  no  work  is  done 
is  one  hundred  and  twenty  thousand  pounds  loss  to  the  deluded 


NOTES  ON  CHAPTER  IV  261 

people"  (Abstract  of  the  Draft  of  a  Bill  for  relieving,  reforming  and 
employing  the  Poor,  1717).  See  also  Defoe,  in  his  Enquiry  into  Occa- 
sional Conformity,  1702,  pp.  18-19.  "We  wonder,  gentlemen,  you  will 
accept  our  money  on  your  deficient  funds,  our  stocks  to  help  carry 
on  your  wars,  our  loans  and  credits  to  your  victualling  office  and 
navv  office  If  you  would  go  on  to  distinguish  us,  get  a  law  made  we 
shall  buy  no  lands,  that  we  may  not  be  freeholders,  and  see  if  you 
could  find  money  to  buy  us  out  Transplant  us  into  towns  and  bodies, 
and  let  us  trade  by  our  selves,  let  us  card,  spin,  knit,  weave  and  work 
with  and  for  one  another,  and  see  how  you'll  maintain  your  own  poor 
without  us  Let  us  fraight  our  ships  apart,  keep  our  money  out  of 
your  Bank,  accept  none  of  our  bills,  and  separate  your  selves  as 
absolutely  from  us  in  civil  matters,  as  we  do  from  you  in  religious, 
and  see  how  you  can  go  on  without  us  " 
24  Swift,  Examiner 

"  Bolmsbroke,  Letter  to  Sir  Wm    Windham,  1753,  p   21 
20  Reliquiae  Baxtenannce  (see  note  2),  p   04  He  goes  on    "The  gen- 
erality of  the  Master  Workmen   [i  e ,  employers]   lived  but  a  little 
better  than  their  journeymen  (from  hand  to  mouth),  but  only  that 
they  laboured   not   altogether  so   hard " 

27  Voltaire,  Lettres  Philosophiques,  no    x,  and  Montesquieu,  Esprit 
des  Lois,  xix,  27,  and  xx,  22    See  also  the  remarks  to  the  same  effect 
in  D'Argenson,  Considerations  sur  le   Gouvernement   de  la  France, 
1765 

28  Brief  Survey  of  the  Growth  of  Usury  in  England,  1673. 
"Marston,  Eastward  Hoi,  act  1,  sc   i 

30  Clarendon,  History  of  the  Rebellion,  bk    i,  par    163. 

81  Petty,  Political  Arithmetic,   16QO,   p    23 

88  Max  Weber,  Die  protestanttsche  Ethik  und  der  Geist  des  Kapi- 
talismus,  first  published  in  the  ArcJmv  fur  Sozialwissenschajt  und  So- 
zmlpohtik  Statistik,  vols  xx,  xxi,  and  since  reprinted  in  vol  i  of  his 
Gesammelte  Aufsatze  zur  Rehgionssozwlogie,  1920,  Troeltsch,  Die 
Soziallehren  der  Chnstlichen  Kirchen  and  Protestantism  ond  Pt ogress, 
1012 ,  Schulze-Gaevernitz,  Bnttscher  Imperialisms  'und  Englischer 
Freihandel,  1906 ,  Cunningham,  Christianity  and  Economic  Science, 
1914,  chap  v 

Weber's  essay  gave  rise  to  much  discussion  in  Germany  Its  main 
thesis — that  Calvinism,  and  in  particular  English  Puritanism,  from 
which  nearly  all  his  illustrations  are  drawn,  played  a  part  of  pre- 
ponderant importance  in  creating  moral  and  political  conditions  favor- 
able to  the  growth  of  capitalist  enterprise — appears  to  be  accepted  by 
Troeltsch,  Die  Soziallehren  der  Chnstlichen  Ktrchen,  pp  70-4  seqq.  It 
is  submitted  to  a  critical  analysis  by  Brentano  (Die  Anfange  des  mo- 
dernen  Kapitahsmus,  1916,  pp  117-57),  who  dissents  from  many  of 
Weber's  conclusions  Weber's  essay  is  certainly  one  of  the  most  fruit- 
ful examinations  of  the  relations  between  religion  and  social  theory 
which  has  appeared,  and  I  desire  to  acknowledge  my  indebtedness 
to  it,  in  particular  with  reference  to  its  discussion  of  the  economic 
application  given  by  some  Puritan  writers  to  the  idea  expressed  by 
the  word  "calling"  At  the  same  time,  there  are  several  points  on 
which  Weber's  arguments  appear  to  me  to  be  one-sided  and  over* 


262  NOTES 

strained,  and  on  which  Brentano's  criticisms  of  it  seem   to  me  to 
be  sound 

Thus  (i),  as  was  perhaps  inevitable  m  an  essay  dealing  with  eco- 
nomic and  social  thought,  as  distinct  from  changes  in  economic  and 
social  organization,  Weber  seems  to  me  to  explain  by  reference  to 
moral  and  intellectual  influences  developments  which  have  their 
principal  explanation  in  another  region  altogether  There  was  plenty 
of  the  "capitalist  spirit"  in  fifteenth-century  Venice  and  Florence,  or 
in  south  Germany  and  Flanders,  for  the  simple  reason  that  these  areas 
were  the  greatest  commercial  and  financial  centers  of  the  age,  though 
all  were,  at  least  nominally,  Catholic  The  development  of  capitalism 
in  Holland  and  England  in  the  sixteenth  and  seventeenth  centuries 
was  due,  not  to  the  fact  that  they  were  Protestant  powers,  but  to 
large  economic  movements,  in  particular  the  Discoveries  and  the  re- 
sults which  flowed  from  them  Of  course  material  and  psychological 
changes  went  together,  and  of  course  the  second  reacted  on  the  first 
But  it  seems  a  little  artificial  to  talk  as  though  capitalist  enterprise 
could  not  appear  till  religious  changes  had  produced  a  capitalist 
spirit  It  would  be  equally  true  and  equally  one-sided,  to  say  that 
the  religious  changes  were  purely  the  result  of  economic  movements 

(n)  Weber  ignores,  or  at  least  touches  too  lightly  on,  intellectual 
movements,  which  were  favorable  to  the  growth  of  business  enter- 
prise and  to  an  individualist  attitude  towards  economic  relations,  but 
which  had  little  to  do  with  religion  The  political  thought  of  the 
Renaissance  was  one,  as  Brentano  points  out,  Machiavelli  was  at 
least  as  powerful  a  solvent  of  traditional  ethical  restraints  as  Calvin 
The  speculations  of  business  men  and  economists  on  mone\,  prices 
and  the  foreign  exchanges  were  a  second  Both  contributed  to  the 
temper  of  single-minded  concentration  on  pecuniary  gain,  which 
Weber  understands  by  the  capitalist  spirit 

(iii)  He  appears  greatly  to  over-simplify  Calvinism  itself  In  the 
first  place,  he  apparently  ascribes  to  the  English  Puritans  of  the  sev- 
enteenth century  the  conception  of  social  ethics  held  by  Calvin  and 
his  immediate  followers  In  the  second  place,  he  speaks  as  though  all 
English  Puritans  m  the  seventeenth  century  held  much  the  same  view 
of  social  duties  and  expediency  Both  suggestions  are  misleading  On 
the  one  hand,  the  Calvmists  of  the  sixteenth  century  (including  Eng- 
lish Puritans)  were  believers  in  a  rigorous  movement  m  its  later 
phases  would  have  horrified  them  The  really  significant  question  is 
that  of  the  causes  of  the  change  from  one  standpoint  to  the  other, 
a  question  which  Weber  appears  to  ignore  On  the  other  hand,  there 
were  within  seventeenth-century  Puritanism  a  variety  of  elements, 
which  held  widely  different  views  as  to  social  policy  As  Cromwell 
discovered,  there  was  no  formula  which  would  gather  Puritan  aristo- 
crats and  Levellers,  landowners  and  Diggeis,  merchants  and  artisans, 
buff-coat  and  his  general,  into  the  fold  of  a  single  social  theory  The 
issue  between  divergent  doctrines  was  fought  out  within  the  Puritan 
movement  itself  Some  won ,  others  lost 

Both  "the  capitalist  spirit''  and  "Protestant  ethics,"  therefore,  were 
a  good  deal  more  complex  than  Weber  seems  to  imply  What  is  true 
and  valuable  in  his  essay  is  his  insistence  that  the  commercial  classes 
in  seventeenth-century  England  were  the  standard-bearers  of  a  par- 


NOTES  ON  CHAPTER  IV  263 

ticular  conception  of  social  expediency,  which  was  markedly  different 
from  that  of  the  more  conservative  elements  in  society — 'the  peasants, 
the  craftsmen,  and  many  landed  gentry — and  that  that  conception 
found  expression  in  religion,  in  politics,  and,  not  least,  in  social  and 
economic  conduct  and  policy. 

33  Cunningham,  The  Moial  Witness  of  the  Church  on  the  Invest- 
ment oj  Money  and  the  Use  of  Wealth,  1009,  p  25 

a*  Knox,  The  Buke  of  Discipline,  in  Works,  ed  D  Lamg,  vol.  ii, 
1848,  pp.  183  seqq.;  Thos  Cartwright,  A  Directory  of  Church  Gov- 
ernment (printed  in  D.  Neal,  History  of  the  Puutan\,  1822,  vol.  v, 
Appx  iv) ,  W  Travers,  A  Full  and  Plain  Declaration  oj  hi  clesiasttcai 
Discipline,  1574,  J  Udall,  A  Demonstration  of  the  Trurth  of  that 
Discipline  which  Chnste  hath  prescribed  in  his  Worde  for  the  Gov- 
ernment of  his  Church,  1589,  Bancroft,  Dangetou*  Positions  and  Pro- 
ceedmgs  Published  and  practiced  within  this  Hand  of  Brytaine  under 
Pretence  of  Reformation  and  for  the  Prc\byte<ia  t  Dtsctpune,  15Q3 
(part  reprinted  in  R  G  Usher,  The  Presbyterian  Movement  in  the 
Reign  oj  Queen  Elizabeth,  as  illustrated  by  the  Minute  book  oj  the 
Dedham  Claris,  1005). 

J0  Cartwnght,  op.  at. 

36  Usher,  op   cit ,  p    1 

37  Ibid ,  pp    14-15,  for  Bancroft's  account  of  the  procedure 

w  Quoted  from  Bailhe's  Letters  by  W  A  Shaw,  A  History  of  the 
English  Church  during  the  Ciml  Wars  and  under  the  Commonwealth, 
1QOO,  vol  i,  p.  128 

3<t  Shaw,  op  cit.,  vol.  ii,  chap  m  (The  Presbyterian  System,  1646- 
60)  For  the  practical  working  of  Presbyterian  discipline,  see  Chet- 
ham  Society,  vols  xx,  xxu,  xxiv,  Minutes  of  the  Manchester  Classis, 
and  vols  xxxvi,  xli,  Minutes  oj  the  bury  Classic 

40  See    Chap    III,   p.    142. 

4 '  Puritan  Manifestoes,  p  1 20,  quoted  by  H  G  Wood,  The  Influ- 
ence of  the  Reformation  on  Ideas  concerning  Wealth  and  Property,  in 
Property,  its  Rights  and  Duties,  1911,  p  142  Mr  Wood's  essay  con- 
tains an  excellent  discussion  of  the  whole  subject,  and  I  should  like 
here  to  acknowledge  rm  obligations  to  it  For  the  views  of  Knew- 
stub,  Smith,  and  Baro,  see  the  quotations  from  them  printed  by 
Haweis,  Sketches  of  the  Reformation,  1844,  pp  237-40,  243-6.  It 
should  be  noted  that  Baro,  while  condemning  those  who,  "sitting 
idle  at  home,  make  merchandise  only  of  their  money,  by  giving  it 
out  in  this  sort  to  needy  persons  without  having  any  regard  of 

his  commodity  to  whomc  they  give  it,  but  only  of  their  own  gain/' 
nevertheless  admitted  that  interest  was  not  always  to  be  condemned. 
See  also  Thos  Fuller,  History  of  the  University  of  Cambridge.,  ed.  M 
Pnckett  and  T  Wright,  1840,  pp  275-6,  288-0,  and  Cunningham, 
Growth  of  English  Industry  and  Commerce,  Modern  Times,  1921 
ed ,  pt  i,  pp  157-8. 

42  New  Shakespeare  Society,  Series  vi,  no  6,  1877-9,  Phillip  Stubbes's 
Anatomy  of  the  Abuses  in  England,  ed    F    J    Furnivall,  pp    115-16, 

43  W    Ames,  De  Conscientia  et  ems  iure  vel  casihus  hbri  quinque, 
bk   v,  chaps   xlui,  Ixiv   Ames  (1576-1633)  was  educated  at  Christ's 
College,  Cambridge,  tried  to  settle  at  Colchester,  but  was  forbidden 
to  preach  by  the  Bishop  of  London,  went  to  Leyden  about  1610, 


264  NOTES 

Was  appointed  to  the  theological  chair  at  Franeker  in  1622,  where  he 
remained  for  ten  years,  and  died  at  Rotterdam 

44  E.g ,  Stubbcs,  op   at  ;  Richard  Capel,  Temptations,  their  Nature, 
Danger,  Cure,  1633,  John  Moore,  The  Ciymg  Sin  of  hngland  of  not 
coring  for  the  Poor,   wherein  Inclosure,  viz    such  as  doth  unpeople 
Townes,  and  uncorn  Fields,  is  arraigned,  convided  and  condemned, 
1653 

46 J  0  Holhwell,  The  Autobiography  and  Correspondence  of  Sir 
Simonds  D'hive\,  1845,  vol  i,  pp  206-10,  322,  354,  vol  n,  pp  %, 
153-4 

4(5  Usher,  op    cil    (sec  note  34  above),  pp    32,  5%  70,  Qo_ioo 
47  Sept   26,  16-J5,  it  is  resolved  "that  it  shall  be  in  the  power  of  the 
eldership  to  suspend  from  the  sacrament  of  the  Lord's  supper  any 
person  that  shall  be  legalh   attainted  of  Barratrv,  loigerv,  Extortion, 
Perjury,  or  Bribery"   ((  ommons'  Journals,  vol    iv,  p    200) 

45  Chetham    Society,    Minuter    of    the    Bury    Presbyterian    Classis, 
1647-57,  pt   i,  pp   32-3    The  Cambridge  dassis  (ibid  ,  pt   n,  pp   106-7) 
decided  in  1657  that  the  oidmance  of  Pailiament  of  August  20,  1648 
Should  be  taken  as  the  rule  of  the  classis  in  the  matter  of  scandal 
The  various  ^candals  mentioned  in  the  ordinance  included  extortion, 
and  the  cla^is  decided  that  "no  person  LiwlulK    convicted  ot  any  of 
the   foresaid   scandalls  bee   admitted   to   the   Lord's   supper   without 
signification  of  sincere  repentance,"  but  it  appears  (p    108)  to  have 
been  mainly  interested  in  witches,  wizards,  and  fortune-tellers 

49  Hut  MSS  Comm  ,  Repoit  on  MSS  m  various  Collections,  vol 
i,  1901,  p  132 

00  Quoted  bv  F  J  Powicke,  A  Life  of  the  Reverend  Richard 
Baxter,  1024,  p  02 

"Selections   irom    these   parts   of    The    Christian    Dirtriorv    which 
bear  on  social  ethics  are  printed  by  Jeannette  Tawne\,  Chapters  from 
Richard  Barter's   Christian   Directory,    1025,   in    which    most    of   the 
passages  quoted  in  the  text  will  be  found 
B<*  Reliqum1  Baxteriano?  (see  note  2),  p  I 

83  Life  and  Death  of  Mr.  Badman  (Cambridge  Knrl^h  Classics, 
1Q05),  pp  116-25,  where  Bunyan  discusses  at  length  the  ethics  of 
prices 

64  Carlyle,   Cromwell'**   Letters  and  Speeches,   Letter   n 
"See  on  these  points  Weber,  op   at.  (note  32  above),  p   04,  whose 
mam  conclusions  1  paraphrase 

^Milton,  A  Defence  of  the  People  of  England  (1602  ed),  p    xvii 

67 See,  eg,  Thos    Wilson,  A   Discourse  upon   U\ury,  Preface,   1025 

ed  ,  p    178     'There  bee  two  sortes  of  men  that  are  al waves  to  bee 

looked  upon  very  narroly,  the  one  is  the  dissembling  gospeller,  and 

the  other  is  the  wilfull  and  indurate  papiste    The  first  under  colour 

of  religion  overthroweth  all  religion,  and  bearing  good  men  in  hande 

that  he  loveth  playnesse,  useth  covertelie  all  deceypte  that  mave  bee, 

and  for  pryvate   gayne  undoeth   the  common   welfaie  ot   man    And 

touching  thys  smne  of  usune,  none  doe  more  openlv  offende  in  thys 

behalfe  than  do  these  counterfeite  professours  of  thys  pure  religion  " 

MFenton,  A   Treatise  of  Uwrie,  1612,  pp    60-1 

60  Brief  Survey  of  the  Growth  of  Usury  in  England,  1673 

*S.  Richardson,  The  Cause  of  the  Poor  Pleaded,  1653,  Thoma&on 


NOTES  ON  CHAPTER  IV  26S 

Tracts,  E  703  (9),  p  14  For  other  references,  see  note  72  below. 
For  extortionate  prices,  see  Thomason  Tracts,  E  390  (6),  The  Worth 
of  a  Penny,  or  a  Caution  to  keep  Money,  1647  I  am  indebted  for 
this  and  subsequent  references  to  the  Thomason  Tracts  to  Miss  P. 
James 

61  Hooker,  Preface  to  The  Laws  of  Ecclesiastical  Polity,  Everyman 
ed  ,  1007,  vol  i,  p  128 

"'Wilson,  op    at,  p    250 

fci  Memoirs  of  the  Life  of  Colonel  Hutchmson,  written  by  his  Widow 
Lucy,  Everyman  ed  ,  1008,  pp  64-5 

04  See   the   references  given   in   note   66 

*'The  Earl  of  Sti afforded  Letter  and  Despatches,  by  William 
Knowler,  DD,  1739  vol  11,  p  138 

0(1  No  attempt  has  been  made  in  the  text  to  do  more  than  refer  to 
the  points  on  which  the  economic  interests  and  outlook  of  the  com- 
mercial and  propertied  classes  brought  them  into  collision  with  the 
monarchy,  and  only  the  most  obvious  sources  of  mlormation  are 
mentioned  here  For  patents  and  monopolies,  including  the  hated  soap 
monopoly,  see  G  Unwin,  The  Gilds  and  Companies  of  London,  1908, 
chap  xvn,  and  W  ll\de  Price,  The  Engh\h  Patents  of  Monopoly, 
1006,  chap  xi,  and  passim  For  the  control  of  exchange  business, 
Cambium  Regis,  or  the  Office  of  his  Majesties  Exchange  Royall,  de- 
claring and  justifying  his  Majesties  Right  and  the  Convenience 
thereof,  1628,  and  Ruding,  Annals  of  the  Coinage,  1810,  vol  iv,  pp. 
201-10  For  the  punishment  of  speculation  by  the  Star  Chamber,  and 
ior  projects  of  public  granaries,  Camden  Society,  N  S  ,  vol  xxxix, 
1886,  Reports  of  Cases  in  the  Courts  of  Star  Chamber  and  High 
Commission,  ed  S  R  Gai diner,  pp  43  seqq  ,  82  seqq ,  and  NSB. 
Onis,  The  Evolution  of  the  English  Corn  Market,  191^  pp  246-50. 
For  the  control  of  the  textile  industry  and  the  reaction  against  it, 
H  Heaton,  The  Yorkshire  Woollen  and  Worsted  Industries,  1920, 
chaps  iv,  vn,  Kate  E  Barford,  The  West  of  England  Cloth  Indus- 
try A  seventeenth-century  Experiment  in  State  Control,  in  the 
Wiltshire  Aichaplogical  and  Natural  History  Magazine,  Dec,  1924,  pp. 
531-42,  R  R  Reid,  The  King's  Council 'in  the  Noith,  1921,  pt  iv, 
chap  11,  Victoria  County  History,  Suffolk,  vol  11,  pp  263-8  For  the 
intervention  of  the  Privy  Council  to  raise  the  wages  of  textile  work- 
ers and  to  protect  craftsmen,  Tawney,  The  Assessment  of  Wages  in 
England  by  the  Justices  of  the  Peace,  in  the  Vierteljahrschrift  fur 
Sozial-  und  Wuthschaftzgeschichte,  Bd  xi,  ion,  pp  307-37,  533-64; 
Leonard,  The  Early  History  of  English  Poor  Relief,  pp  160-3;  Vic- 
toria County  History,  Suffolk,  vol  n,  pp  268-9,  and  Unwin,  Indus- 
trial Organization  in  thv  Sixteenth  and  Seventeenth  Centuries,  1904, 
pp  142-7  For  the  Depopulation  Commissions,  Tawney,  The  Agrarian 
Problem  m  the  Sixteenth  Century,  pp  376,  391  For  the  squeezing 
of  money  from  the  East  India  Company  and  the  infringement  of  its 
Charter,' Shafa 'at  Ahmad  Khan,  The  East  India  Trade  m  the  XVIlth 
Century,  1023,  pp  60-73  For  the  colonial  interests  of  Puritan  mem- 
bers, A  P  Newton,  Th(  Colonising  Attivities  of  the  English  Puritans, 
1914,  and  C  E  Wade,  John  Pym,  1912. 

07  E  Laspeyres,  Geschichte  der  Volkswirthschajtlichen  Anschauun- 
gen  der  Niederlander  und  ihrer  Literatur  zur  Zeit  der  Republik, 


266  NOTES 

1863,  pp  256-70  An  idea  of  the  points  at  issue  can  be  gathered  from 
the  exhaustive  (and  unreadable)  work  of  Salmasms,  De  Modo 
Vsurarum,  1639 

68  John  Quick,  Synodicon  in  Gallia  Reformata,  1692,  vol   i,  p    99. 

w  For  the  change  of  sentiment  in  America,  see  Troeltsch,  Protes- 
tantism and  Progress,  pp.  117-27;  for  Franklin,  Memoirs  of  the  Life 
and  Writings  of  Benjamin  Franklin,  and  Sombart,  The  Quintessence 
Of  Capitalism,  1915,  pp.  116-21 

70  Rev.  Robert  Woodrow  (quoted  by  Sombart,  op.  cit ,  p    149). 

71  John    Cooke,    Unum    Necessanum    or    the    Poore    Man's    Case 
(1648),  which  contains  a  plea  for  the  regulation  of  prices  and  the 
establishment  of  Monts  de  Picte 

"For  the  scandal  caused  to  the  Protestant  religion  by  its  alleged 
condonation  of  covetousness,  see  T  Watson,  A  Plea  for  Alms,  1658 
(Thomason  Tracts,  E  2125),  pp  21,  33-4  "The  Church  of  Rome 
layes  upon  us  this  aspersion  that  we  are  against  good  workes 
I  am  sorry  that  any  who  go  for  honest  men  should  be  brought  into 
the  mdightment,  I  mean  that  any  professors  should  be  impeached  as 
guilty  of  this  sinne  of  covctousnesse  and  unmercifalne^se  .  .  I  tell 
you  these  devout  misers  are  the  reproach  of  Christianity  ...  I  may 
say  of  penurious  votaries,  they  have  the  wings  of  profession  by  which 
they  seem  to  fly  to  heaven,  but  the  feet  of  beasts,  walking  on  the 
earth  and  even  licking  the  dust  .  Oh,  take  heed,  that,  seeing  your 
religion  will  not  destroy  your  covetousnesse,  at  last  your  covetous- 
nesse  does  not  destroy  your  religion  "  See  also  Sir  Balthazar  Gerbier, 
A  New  Year's  Result  in  favour  of  the  Poore,  1651  (Thomason  Tracts, 
E.  651  [14],  p  4  "If  the  Papists  did  rely  as  much  on  faith  as  the 
reformed  professors  of  the  Gospel  (according  to  our  English  tenets) 
doe,  or  that  the  reformed  professors  did  so  much  practice  charity  as 
the  Papists  doe?" 

"S.  Richardson,  op.  at    (see  note  60  above),  pp    7-8,   10 

T4The  first  person  to  emphasize  the  way  in  which  the  idea  of  a 
*  calling"  was  used  as  an  argument  for  the  economic  virtues  was 
Weber  (see  note  32  above),  to  whose  conclusions  I  am  largely  in- 
debted for  the  following  paragraphs 

"  Bunyan,  The  Pilgrim's  Progress 

"Steele,  op.  at.   (see  note   76  above) 

Richard  Steele,  The  Tradesman's  Calling,  being  a  Discourse  con- 
cerning the  Nature,  Necessity,  Choice,  etc,  of  a  Calling  in  general, 
1684,  pp  1,  4 

"  Ibid.,   pp.   21-2. 

78  Ibid,  p   35 

19  Baxter,  Christian  Directory,   1678  ed ,  vol    i,  p    3366. 

80  Thomas  Adams  (quoted  Weber,  op.  cit ,  p   96  n  ) 

$1  Matthew  Henry,  The  Worth  of  the  Soul  (quoted  ibid.,  p   168  n.). 

"Baxter,  op    cit,  vol    i,  p.  Ilia. 

"Steele,  op.  cit,  p.  20 

84  Baxter,  op.  at»  vol   i,  pp.  3786,  1086,  vol.  iv,  p.  2530. 


NOTES  ON  CHAPTER  IV  267 

8G  Navigation  Spiritualized:  or  a  New  Compass  for  Seamen,  con- 
sisting of  xxxn  Points 

I  Pleasant  Observation* 
of  v   Profitable  Applications  and 
I  Serious  Reflections 

All  concluded  with  so  many  spiritual  poems    Whereunto  is  now  added, 

i  A  sober  conversation  of  the  sm  of  drunkenness. 
n  The  Harlot's  face  in  the  script  lire -glass,  etc 

Being  an  essay  towards  then  much  dewed  Reformation  from  the  hor- 
rible and  detestable  sins  of  Drunkenness,  Swearing,  Uncleanness,  For- 
get fulness  of  Meicies,  Violation  of  Promises,  and  Atheistical  Contempt 
of  Death  1682 

The  author  of  this  cheerful  work  wa«  a  Devonshire  minister,  John 
Flavell,  who  also  wrote  Husbandry  Spiritualized,  or  the  Heavenly 
Use  of  Earthly  Things,  1660  In  him,  as  in  Steele,  the  Chadband 
touch  is  unmistakable  The  Religious  Weaver,  apparently  by  one 
Fawcett,  I  have  not  been  able  to  trace 

80 Steele,   op    cit    (see  note   76  above) 

87  Bunyan,  The  Pilgrim's  Progress 

*s  David  Jones,  A  Farewell  Sermon  at  St    Mary  Woolnoth's,  1692 

hM  Nicholas  Barbon,  A  Discourse  of  Trade,  1600,  ed  by  Professor 
John  H  Hollander  (A  Reprint  of  Economic  Tracts,  Series  11,  no  I). 

uo  The  words  of  a  member  of  the  Long  Parliament,  quoted  by 
C  H  Fnth,  Oliver  Cromwell,  1002,  p  31  ^ 

01  The  Life  of  Edward,  Earl  of  Clarendon,  1827  ed  ,  vol  11,  p  2^5. 
"The  merchants  took  much  delight  to  enlarge  themselves  upon  this 
argument  he  ,  the  advantages  of  war],  and  shortly  after  to  discourse 
'of  the  infinite  benefit  that  would  accrue  from  a  barefaced  war  against 
the  Dutch,  how  easily  they  might  be  subdued  and  the  trade  carried 
by  the  English  '  "  According  to  Clarendon,  who  despised  the  mer- 
chants and  hated  the  whole  business,  it  was  almost  a  classical  example 
of  a  commercial  war,  carciully  stage-managed  in  all  its  details,  from 
the  directorship  which  the  Royal  African  Company  gave  to  the  Duke 
of  York  down  to  the  inevitable  "incident"  with  which  hostilities 
began 

92  Ibid  ,  vol    in,  pp    7-9 

IH  Sir  Dudley  North,  Discourses  upon  Trade,  1691,  Preface 

M  Petty,  Political  Arithmetic,  Preface 

nr>  Chamberlayne,  Anglioz  Notitia  (quoted  P  E  Dove,  Account  of 
Andrew  Yarranton,  1854,  p  82  n). 

f'°  Roger  North,  The  Lives  of  the  Norths  (1826  ed  ),  vol  in,  p  103; 
T  Watson,  A  Plea  for  Alms  (Thomason  Tracts,  E  2125),  p.  33; 
Dryden,  Absalom  and  Achitophel,  2nd  part,  1682,  p  9,  where  Sir 
Robert  Clayton,  Lord  Mayor  1670-80,  and  Member  of  Parliament  for 
the  City  1679-81  and  again  from  1689,  appears  as  "extorting  Ish- 
ban  "  He  was  a  scrivener  who  had  made  his  money  by  usury 

fl7  John  Fawke,  Sir  William  Thompson,  William  Love  and  John 
Jones 

98  Charles  King  (The  British  Merchant,  1721,  vol.  i,  p    181)  gives 


268  NOTES 

the  following  persons  as  signatories  of  an  analysis  of  the  trade  be- 
tween England  and  France  in  1674  *  Patience  Ward,  Thomas  Papillon, 
James  Houblon,  William  Bellamy,  Michael  Godfrey,  George  Tonano, 
John  Houblon,  John  Houghe,  John  Mervin,  Peter  Paravicine,  John 
Dubois,  Benj.  Godfrey,  Edm  Harrison,  Benj.  Delaune  The  number 
of  foreign  names  is  remarkable 

MFor  Dutch  capital  in  London,  see  Hist  MSS  Comm  ,  8th  Report, 
1881,  p.  134  (proceedings  of  the  Committee  on  the  decay  of  trade, 
1669) ;  with  regard  to  investment  of  foreign  capital  in  England,  it  was 
stated  that  "Alderman  Bucknell  had  above  £100,000  in  his  hands, 
Mr.  Meynell  above  £30,000,  Mr.  Vandeput  at  one  time  £60,000,  Mr. 
Dencost  always  near  £200,000  of  Dutch  money,  lent  to  merchants 
at  7,  6,  and  5  per  cent  " 

100  The  Life  of  Edward,  Earl  of  Clarendon,  vol  11,  pp  289-93,  and 
vol.  iii,  pp  4-7;  and  John  Beresford,  The  Godfather  of  Downing 
Street,  1925 

101 S.  Bannister,  William  Paterson,  the  Merchant-Statesman,  and 
founder  of  the  Bank  of  England  His  Life  and  Trials,  1858 

102  A.   Yarranton,  England's   Improvement,    1677 

108  The  Complete  English    Tradesman    (1726)    belongs  to   the   same 
genus  as  the  book  of  Steele  (see  abo\e,  pp   244-6),  but  it  has  reduced 
Christianity  to  even  more  innocuous  proportions    see  Letter  xvu  (Of 
Honesty  in  Dealing) 

104  T.  S.  Ashton,  Iron  and  Steel  in  the  Industrial  Revolution,  1Q24, 
pp.  211-26  Mr  A  P  Wadsworth  has  shown  that  the  leading  Lan- 
cashire colthiers  were  often  Nonconformists  (History  of  the  Roch- 
dale Woollen  Trade,  in  Trans  Rochdale  Lit  and  Sci  Soc ,  vol  xv, 
1925). 

100  Quoted  F   J   Powicke,  Life  of  Baxter,  1924,  p    158 

106  Dicey,  Law  and  Public  Opinion  m  England,  1005,  pp    400-1 

107  The  Humble  Petition  of  Thousands  of  well-iff<>cted  Persons  in- 
habiting the  City  of  London,  Westminster,  th*c  Borough   of  South- 
wark,  Hamlets,  and  Places  adjacent   (Bodleian  Pamphlets,  The  Level- 
lers' Petitions,  c    15,  3  Line  )    See  also  G    P    Gooch,  English  Demo- 
cratic Ideas  in  the  Seventeenth  Century,  1808 

J<*Camden  Society,  The  Clarke  Papers,  ed  C  H  Firth,  1891-4,  vol 
ii,  pp.  217-21  (letter  from  Winstanley  to  Fairfax  and  the  Council  of 
War,  Dec  8,  1649) 

109  Records  of  the  Borough  of  Leicester,  1603-88,  ed    Helen  Stocks, 
1923,  pp    370,  414,  428-30 

110  John  Moore,  op  cit    (see  note  44,  above),  p   13   See  also  E   C   K 
Conner,  Common  Land  and  Enclosure,  1912,  pp    5^-5 

111  Camden  Society,  The  Clarke  Papers,  vol    i,  pp    299  seqq  ,  Ixvii 
seqq 

112  The  Diary  of  Thomas  Burton,  ed    J    T    Rutt,  1828,  vol    i,  pp 
175-6.  A  letter  from  Whalley,  referring  to  agitations  against  enclosure 
in   Warwickshire,    Nottinghamshire,    Lincolnshire    and    Leicestershire, 
will  be  found  in  Thurloe,  State  Papers,  vol   iv,  p   686 

118  Joseph  Lee,  A  Vindication  of  a  Regulated  Enclosure,  1656,  p    9. 

114  Aquinas,  Summa  Theol ,  2a  2l«,  Q  xxxn,  art  v 

118  Dives  et  Pauper,  1493,  Prol ,  chap,  vn,  cf.  Pecock,  The  Represser 


NOTES  ON  CHAPTER  IV  269 

of  over-much  Blaming  of  the  Clergy,  pt.  iii,  chap  iv,  pp.  296-7.  For 
an  excellent  account  of  the  medieval  attitude  towards  the  poor,  see 
B.  L  Manning,  The  People's  Faith  in  the  Time  of  Wycltf,  1919,  chap.  x. 

116  A  Lyke-wake  Dirge,  printed  by  W.  Allmgham,  The  Ballad  Book, 
1007,  no  xxxi 

"'  Latimer,  The  fifth  Sermon  on  the  Lord's  Prayer  (in  Sermons, 
Everyman  ed ,  p  ^36)  Cf  Tyndale,  The  Parable  of  the  Wicked 
Mammon  (in  Doctrinal  Treaties  of  William  Tyndale,  Parker  Society, 
1848,  p.  97)  "If  thy  brother  or  neighbour  therefore  need,  and  thou 
have  to  help  him,  and  vet  showest  not  mercy,  but  withdrawest  thy 
hands  from  him,  then  robbest  thou  him  of  his  own,  and  art  a  thief." 

118  Christopher  Harvey,  The  Overseer  of  the  Poor  (in  G.  Gilfillan, 
The  Poetical  Work1,  of  George  Herbert,  1853,  pp  241-3) 

"*  J  E  B  Mayor,  Two  Live*  of  JV  Ferrar,  by  his  brother  John 
and  Dr  Jebb,  p  261  (quoted  bv  B  Kirkman  Gray,  A  History  of 
English  Philanthropy,  1Q05,  p  54) 

Uo  A  True  Report  of  the  Great  Cost  and  Charges  of  the  foure 
Hospitals  m  the  City  of  London,  164-4  (quoted,  ibid ,  p  66) 

lal  See,  eg,  Hist  MSS  Comm  ,  Reports  on  MSS  in  various  Col- 
lections,  vol  i,  1Q01,  pp  109-24,  Leonard,  Early  History  of  English 
Poor  Relief,  pp  268-9 

122  Sir  Matthew  Hale,  A  Discourse  touching  Provision  for  the 
Poor,  1683 

^Stanley's  Remedy,  or  the  Way  how  to  reform  wandering  Beg- 
gars, Thieves,  Highway  Robbers  and  Pick-pockets,  1646  (Thomason 
Tracts,  E  317  [6]),  p  4 

^Commons'  Journals,  March  19,  1648/9,  vol    vi,  p    167. 

12*lbtd,  vol    vi,  pp    201,  374,  416,  481,  vol    vn,  p    167. 

J'(1  Samuel  Hartlib,  London's  Charity  Inlarged,  1650,  p.  i. 

127  Harthb,  op    at 

12N  Firth  and  Rait,  Acts  and  Ordinances  of  the  Interregnum,  1911, 
vol  11,  pp  104-10  An  ordinance  creating  a  corporation  had  been 
passed  Dec  17,  1647  (ibid,  vol  i,  pp  1042-5) 

12U  Ibid ,  vol    11,  pp    10Q8-Q 

1JOStockwood,  at  Paul's  Cross,  1578  (quoted  by  Haweis,  Sketches 
of  the  Reformation,  p  277) 

inSteele,   op    cit     (note   76   above),  p    22 

132  R  Younge,  The  Poorer'  Advocate,  1654  (Thomason  Tracts,  E. 
1452  F3J),  p  6 

1<!For  these  and  olh-jr  passages  from  Restoration  economists  to  the 
same  effect,  see  a  striking  article  by  Dr  T  E  Gregory  on  The  Eco- 
nomics of  Employment  in  England  (1660-1713)  in  Economica,  no.  i, 
Jan,  1921,  pp  S7  seqq  ,  and  E  S  Furniss,  The  Position  of  the  La- 
bourer m  a  System  of  Nationalism,  1920,  chaps  v,  vi 

1M/)as  KommtmistHche  Manifest,  1Q18  ed  ,  pp  27-8  "Die  Bour- 
geoisie, wo  sic  zur  llerrschaft  gekommen,  hat  alle  feudalen,  patriar- 
chalischen,  idyllischen  verhaltmsse  zer«tort  Sie  hat  die  bundscheckigen 
Feudalbande,  die  den  Mcnschen  an  semen  naturlichen  Vorgesetzten 
knupften,  unbarmherzig  zcrnssen,  und  kein  andeies  Band  zwischen 
Mensch  und  Mensch  ubng  gelassen,  als  das  nackte  Interesse,  als  die 
gefuhllose  bare  Zahlung " 

136  Defoe,  Giving  Alms  no  Chanty,  1704,  pp    25-7. 


270  NOTES 

180  Petty,  Political  Arithmetic,  p  45 

187  Sir  Henry  Pollexfen,  Discourse  of  Trade,  1607,  p  40,  Walter 
Harris,  Remarks  on  the  Affairs  and  Trade  of  England  and  Ireland, 
1691,  pp  43-4,  The  Querist,  1737  (in  The  Works  of  George  Berke- 
ley, D.  D.,  ed  A  C  Fraser,  1871,  p  387),  Thomas  Alcock,  Obser- 
vations on  the  Defects  of  the  Poor  Laivs,  1752,  pp  4^  seqq  (quoted 
Furniss,  op  cit ,  p  153) 

138  Arthur  Young,  Eastern  Tour,   1771,  vol    iv,  p    361 

189  Harrison,  The  Description  of  Britame,  1587  ed  ,  bk  11,  chap  x, 
Of  Provision  made  for  the  Poor 

140  H.  Hunter,  Problems  of  Poverty    Selections  from  the          Writ- 
ings of  Thomas  Chalmers,  D    D,  1912,  p    202 

141  For  the  influence  of  Chalmer's  idea  on  Senior,  and,  through  him, 
on  the  new  Poor  Law  of  1834,  see  T  Mackay,  History  of  the  English 
Poor  Law,  vol   ni,  1809,  pp   32-4   Chalmers  held  that  anv  Poor  Law 
was  in  itself  objectionable    Senior,  who  described  Chalmers'  evidence 
before  the  Committee  on  the  State  of  the  Poor  in  Ireland  as  "the 
most  instructive,  perhaps,  that  ever  was  given  before  a  Committee 
of  the  House  of  Commons,"  appears  to  have  begun  by  agreeing  with 
him,  but  later  to  have  adopted  the  principle  of  deterrence,  backed 
by  the  test  workhouse,  as  a  second  best  The  Commissioners  of  1832-4 
were  right  in  thinking  the  existing  methods  of  relief  administration 
extremely  bad,   they   were   wrong   in   supposing   distress  to   be   due 
mainly  to  lax  administration,  instead  of  realizing,  as  was  the  fact, 
that  lax  administration  had  arisen  as  an  attempt  to  meet  the  increase 
of  distress.  Their  discussion  of  the  causes  of  pauperism  is,  therefore, 
extremely  superficial,  and  requires  to  be  supplemented  by  the  evidence 
contained  in  the  various  contemporary  reports   (such,  e  g  ,  as  those 
on  the  hand-loom  weavers)  dealing  with  the  industrial  aspects  of  the 
problem. 

142  W    C    Braithwaite.  The  Second  Period  of  Quakerism,  1910,  pp 
560-2.    Defoe    comments    on    the    strict    business    standards    of    the 
Quakers  in  Letter  xvn   (Of  Honesty  in   Dealing}   in   The   Complete 
English  Tradesman.  Mr    Ashton    (Iron  and  Steel  in   the   Industrial 
Revolution,  p   219)  remarks,  "The  eighteenth  century  Friend  no  less 
than  the  medieval   Catholic   held   firmly   to   some   doctrine   of   Just 
Price,"  and  quotes  examples  from  the  conduct  of  Quaker  iron-masters 


INDEX 


Abbot's  Ripton,   120,  253 
Acton,  Lord,  61 
Acts  of  Parliament 

15  Ed   III,  st.  1,  c.  5  (1341),  51 

37  Hen    VIII,  c    9   (1545),   136 

5   and   6  Ed    VI,  c    20    (1552), 
136,   153 

13   Ehz,  c    8    (1571),   136,   153, 
154,  159 

39  Ehz  ,  c    2   (1597),  152 
Aegidiu*;  Lessmus,  242 
Aeneas  Silvius,   97 
Agriculture,  117-128,  192     See  also 
Enclosures,   Land,   Pasture 
farming,  Peasants 
Alcock,  Thomas,  224 
Alien  immigrants,   170-1,   259 
Almsgiving,    condemnation    of,    98, 

101,  220,  251,   a  duty,  216 
America,  silver  of,  64,  68,  116, 

Calvinism  m,  111-115,   189,   198, 

265 

Ames,   179-80,  262-3 
Amsterdam,  93 
Anglicans     See  Clergy  and  Church 

of  England 
Annuities,  43,  181 
Antwerp,  67-69,  72,  73,  77,  79,  92, 

143,    151,   249,    fall   of,    70,    150 
Apparel,  excess  in  101,  111 
Aquinas     See  St    Thomas 
Archdeacons,    visitations    of,    48-9, 

52,  138,  243-4,  255 
Aristotle,  45 
Asceticism,  23,  24 
Ashton,  T.  S.,  210,  269 
Aske,  121 
Augsburg,  72,  77 

Bacon,  127,  129,  157 

Baillie,   178 

Bancroft,  Archbishop,  158,  177,  178 

Bank,  at  Geneva,  105-6 

— of  England,  209 

Banking,  deposit,  beginnings  of,  150 

Barbon,  Dr    Nicholas,  205 

Barebones,  Praise-God,  205 


Bargaining,  equity  in,  130,  136, 
153-4.  155,  159,  184-6.  203,225-6 
See  also  Prices  and  Profits 

Bdio,  179,  262 

Basle,   105,   Council  of,  92 

Baxter,  Richard,  16,  24,  167,  169, 
172,  182-7,  188,  201,  (quoted), 
202  (quoted),  210,  215,  223,  238 

Becon,  74,  121,  123 

Beggars  See  Almsgiving  and  Va- 
grancy 

Belldrmin,  73,  249 

Bellers,  24,  226 

Belloc,  H  ,  82 

Bennet,  Dr  ,  131 

Benvenuto   da  Imola,   (quoted),   18 

Berkeley,   Bishop,  224,  233 

Beine,  105 

Berthold,  Brother,   187 

Beza,  105,  107,  108,  179 

Birmingham,  169 

Bishops,  articles  of  visitation  of, 
137,  were  normally  justices,  141; 
Bill  re  powers  of,  148-9,  257; 
abolition  of,  159,  178  See  also 
Commissary,  Court  of  fftgh  Com- 
mission and  Courts,  ecclesiastical 

Blaxton,  John,  cited,  134 

Bodin,  74 

Boheim,  Hans,  74 

Bolmgbroke,    172 

Bologna,  University  of,  73 

Boniface  VIII,  24,  bull  of,  26 

Bossuet,  75 

Boston,  112-4 

Bourges,  50 

Braddon,  Lawrence,  259 

Bradford,    169 

— ,  Governor,   111    (quoted),   112 

Brentano,  261 

Bristol,    168 

Brittany,  Count  of,  245 

Bruges,  67 

Bucer,  24,  61,  74,  75,  93,  102,  122 
179 

Bullinger,  24,  74,  101,   153 

Bunyan,  16,  24,  166,  187,  223,  255 


271 


272 


INDEX 


Burford,  154 

Buridanus,  Johannes,  242 

Bury,  181 

Cahorsmes,  33,  240,  243 

''Calling,"   199-204,   260,   265 

Calvin,  16,  24,  84,  01 -US,  teaching 
of,  on  usury,  74,  75,  110,  154, 
179  180,  193,  199,  letter  of,  to 
Somerset,  102,  Institute  of.  102, 
103,  scheme  of  municipal  govern- 
ment drafted  by,  103,  death  of, 
105  See  also  Calvinism 

Calvinism,  91-115,  194-5,  sanctifi- 
cation  of  economic  enterprise  by, 
36-7,  92-3,  95,  96,  07,  98,  102, 
193,  199,  connection  of  individ- 
ualism with,  09-100,  189,  261, 
discipline  of  99,  100,  102-115, 
178-9,  182,  189,  195,  261,  in 
France,  109-10.  in  Scotland,  111, 
development  of,  in  England,  165, 
in  Holland,  175  See  also  Calvin 
and  Puntantsm 

Cambridge,  262 

Canon  law.    See  Law,  canon 

Canonists,  chicanery  and  casuistry 
of,  39,  51,  53,  58,  97  See  also 
Law,  canon 

Canterbury,  171,  archbishop  of,  48, 
133,  Canons  of,  137 

Capitalism,  early  appearance  of,  21- 
2,  30,  76,  188,  connection  of, 
with  Puritanism,  176,  260-2 

Carpenters,  parliament  of,   239 

Cartwnght,    Thomas,    177,    179 

Catholicism,  rind  capitalism,  76,  261 

Cattle,   loaning   of,    53,    132,    154 

Cecil,  William,  124,  141 

Chalmers,   Dr  ,   225     269 

Charles  I,  social  policy  of,  144-8, 
175-195-7,  264 

Charles  V,  66,  72 

Chaucer,   28,    (quoted),   248 

Chauvet,  108 

Chesterton,   G    K  ,  82 

Chevage,  126 

Chevisance,   5 1 

Choisy,  252 

Church,  medieval,  pomp  and  avarice 
of,  57,  58,  59,  attitude  of,  to 
established  social  order,  55-7, 
strength  and  weakness  of,  57-8; 
ideals  of,  58-60 

— of  England,  116-63;  conservatism 
and  ineffectiveness  of  social  theory 


of,     76-7,     132-4,     156-63,     231; 
Puritanism  represented  in,  165 

Church   of  Ireland,   137 

See  also  Clergy,  Councils 
(Church),  Courts  (ecclesiasti- 
cal), Low  (canon),  Papfuy,  Ref- 
ormation, Religion,  and  under 
State 

Churches,  Nonconformist,  attitude 
of,  to  social  pioblems  in  18th  cen- 
tury, 230  See  also  Picsbytcnan- 
tsni,  Puiitanism,  Tolerance 

Civil  La\v       See  Law,  civil 

Clarendon   Code,    170 

- — ,  Constitutions  of,   50 

—     Earl  of,  147,  170    207,209,266 

Class  hatred,   23,    108,    124 

Classes,  Puritan,  177,  181,  261,  262 

Clayton,  Sir  Robert,   266 

Clerg>,  taking  of  usury  by,  33,  46- 
7,  52,  240,  246,  suoservience  of, 
136,  230,  return  of,  to  City 
churches,  170,  popular  sym- 
pathies of,  m  France,  230  See 
also  Church  of  England 

Cloth  industry,  93,  117  122,  126, 
capitalism  in,  65,  150,  222-3, 
distress  in,  143,  170,  2S9,  wages 
in,  148,  240,  264,  regulation  of, 
148,  196,  197,  264,  Puritanism 
in  centers  of,  168,  169,  170,  267, 
proposed  nationalization  of,  106 
See  also  Textile  workers 

Coke,   158 

Colbert,    70,    196 

Cologne,   40 

Colonization,  66,  198,  264 

Colquhoun,  Patrick,  258 

Columbus,    63,    64,    80 

Combinations,  54,  78-0,  85-6,  239- 
40  See  also  Gilds 

Commissary,  Court  of,  52,  138,  246, 
256 

Commissions  Depopulation,  118-9, 
124,  147,  197,  264 

Commons,  enclosure  of,  120,  143, 
148,  212,  215  See  also  hn~ 
closures 

"Commonwealth   men  "    124 
Communal  movement,  55 
Communism,  35,   212 

Companies,  infringement  of  charters 
of,  197     See  also  East  India  Co. 
and  Royal  African  Co 
Confessors,  instructions  to,  49 
Congregationalism^  f  165     "><.  • 


INDEX 


273 


Consistory,  at  Geneva,  102,  103, 
104-9 

Constance,  Council  of,  92 

Consumption,   37,    192,   206,   208 

Copper,  68,  69,   72 

Copyholders,    119,    126,    143,    253 

Corn,  engrossing  of,  108,  143,  148, 
256  See  also  Granaries 

Coulton,  G    G  ,   18,  33 

Councils,  Church,  46-7,  51,  53,  246 

Court,  De  la,   171 

Court  of  Arches,   158 

—chancery,  51,  52,  241,  247 

— Delegates,  158 

—High  Commission,  139,  158,  197, 
258;  abolition  of,  159,  177,  178 

—Requests,   119,  254 

—Star  Chamber,  119,  148,  253, 
256,  257,  264,  abolition  of,  177 

Courts,  jurisdiction  of,  with  regard 
to  usury,  40-1,  50-3,  137-8,  ec- 
clesiastical, 50-3,  137-8,  158-9, 
177-8,  246,  247,  royal,  en- 
croachments of,  on  feudal  system, 
56-7,  78  See  also  the  several 
Courts  above-mentioned 

Coventry,  40,  254 

Craftsmen,  deceits  practiced  by,  28, 
110,  244,  relations  between  mer- 
chants and,  30,  117,  118,  148, 
196,  265,  labor  of,  honorable,  83, 
199  See  also  G/Wv  and  Wage- 
earners 

Cianmer,  75,  137 

Cromwell,  Oliver,   166,   182 
(quoted),   207,   214,   261 

Crowley,  Robert,  74,  121,  123 
( quoted) 

Cunningham,  William,  176,  177 
(quoted) 

Curia,  papal,   47-8 

Currency,  depreciation  of,  70,  71, 
118,  150 

Danzig,  89 

Debtor,    defaulting,    punishment    of, 

111 

Dedham,  classts  of,  181 
Detoe,    170,   210,   260,   268 
Depopulation        See      Commissions 

and   Enclosures 
DEwes,    180 
Dicey,  Prof  ,211 
Diet,    Imperial,    79 
Diggers,  212,  261 
Disc.ioline.   versus    the   Religion   of 


Trade,   176-89     See  also 

tsm,  Presbytenamsm,  Purttanitfk 

Discoveries  63,  64,  68,  77,  78,  116,' 
261 

Dives  et  Pauper,  16,  180,  267 

Downing,  Sir  George,  209 

Duns  Scotus,  36 

Dutch,  virtues  of,  175,  210,  223; 
capital  supplied  to  England  by, 
207,  209,  267,  imitation  of  meth- 
ods of,  209  See  also  Holland 

East  Anglia,  148,  Puritanism  itt» 
168-9 

— India  Co  ,  264 

Kck,   7S 

Economic  Science,  development  of, 
14-7,  72-3,  13S,  1S3,  157,  160, 
170  207-8  See  also  Economists 

Economists,  207,  attitude  of,  to- 
wards religious  tolerance,  17, 
170,  171-2.  attitude  of,  toward^ 
poor  relief,  223-6,  268-9.  See 
also  Economic  Snence 

Edict  of  Nantes,  revocation  of,  17t 

Education,  diffusion  of,  121,  122, 
123,  parochial,  132  See  also 
Schools 

Enclosures,  118-28,  popular  agita- 
tmns  against,  118,  119,  120, 
123-4,  213,  267,  first  account  of, 
119  steps  taken  by  Government 
to  check,  119,  124-6,  147,  152, 
196,  212,  254,  256,  257,  attitude 
of  Puritans  to  180,  186,  196, 
212-16  See  also  under  Gentry 

England,  comparison  of,  with  the 
Continent,  15,  22,  53,  65,  116, 
192 

Engrossers,  38,  39,  40,  42,  54,  105, 
107,  108,  140,  143,  148,  162, 
196,  198,  203,  256,  257 

Erasmus,  67,  70 

Eiastians,  178 

Essex,  138,  168 

Evangelicals,  163,  211 

Exchanger,  Royal,   197 

Exchanges,  foreign,  discussions  ori* 
44,  135,  150-1,  261,  control  ol, 
68,  143,  196,  197,  256,  264;  law-C; 
fulness  of  transactions  on,  73+*4  ' 

Exchequer,  stop  of,  187  ;• 

Exclusion  Bill,  169 

Excommunication,  32,  46,  47,  52^' 
103,  106,  122,  137,  17&,  24&£> 
disregarding  of,  136,  ISO  '\<j 


274 

Exeter,  169,  bishop  of,  144 


INDEX 


Fairs,  46 

Fenton,  Rogei,  quoted,  94 

Ferrar,  Nicholas,  218 

Feudalism,  27,  55-57,  192,  decline 
of,  55-56,  126,  128,  148  See  also 
Peasants 

Figgis,  Dr  ,  13 

Financiers,  medieval  attitude  to,  28, 
36,  93,  international,  rise  of,  67, 
69,  72;  Catholicism  of,  76,  atti- 
tude of  Swiss  reformers  to,  92, 
96  See  also  Usury 

Fir  mm,  226 

Flanders     See  Low  Countries 

Flavell,  John,  266 

Fletcher  of  Saltoun,  220 

Florence,  22,  39,  50,  238,  241,  261 

Foley,  Thomas,  210 

Fonclaco  Tedesco,  63 

Food-supplies,  control  of,  148,  195, 

196,  217-218       See  also  Corn 
Fox,  166,  167 

Foxe,  137 

France,  53,  70,  196,  207,  222,  230, 
240,  248,  259,  peasant! y  m,  56, 
57,  117,  129,  Calvinism  in,  109- 
110,  169,  198  See  also  Lyons 
and  Paris 

Franciscans,  23,  53,  Spiritual,  55 

Franeker,  University  of,  180 

Frankfurt,  30,  69,  77,  97 

Franklin,  Benjamin,  198,  265 

Free  Cities,  55 

Freeholders,  168,  169,  214 

Freiburg,  77 

Friars,  24 

Friends     See  Quakers 

Friesiand,  West,  198 

Froissart,  24 

Froude,  12 

Fruiterers,  of  London,  54 

Fuggers,  the,  72,  73,  74,  79,  81, 
162,  249 

Gay,  Prof,  125 

Geiler  von  Kaiserberg,  79,  250 

Geneva,  92,  99,  101-110,  179,  188, 

189,  195,  252 
Genoa,  48 
Gentry,  opposition  of,  to  prevention 

of  enclosures,  124,  126,  151,  196, 

197,  212-213,  214,  254,  attitude 
of,  to  commercial  classes,  172-175 

George,  Lloyd,  quoted,  12,  237 


Germany,  53,  64,  70,  207;  schemes 
of  social  reconstruction  in,  31, 
79,  248,  peasantry  in,  56,  57,  74, 
75,  78,  79,  82,  83,  117,  119,  129, 
248,  trade  and  banking  business 
of,  64,  65,  68,  69,  72,  77-79,  80- 
81,  201,  Reformation  in,  72,  73- 
74,  75,  77-00,  c>7,  121  wage- 
eainmg  class  in,  in  Middle  \ges, 
78,  239 

Gilds,  membership  of,  30,  policy 
and  ideals  of,  30-32,  enforcement 
of  rules,  52,  256,  loans  by,  53, 
247  capture  of,  by  capitalist 
membeis  64,  78,  117,  control  of, 
at  \ntwerp,  6°,  malpractices  of, 
1 18,  239,  confiscation  of  lands  of, 
120,  254 

Glasgow    198 

dloucestiM     K>0 

GculfHx  ,  Mu  ha  el,  200 

Goldsmiths    207 

Giananes    public     1^6,  264 

Gratia n    35,  3 > 

Grew  \   VII    24 

— ,  Sir   Ihomas,  16,  122,  151     152 

Gnndal,  Archbishop,  137 

Grosstf'te,  Bishop,  33,  240 


Hague,  The,  209 

Hale    Sir  Matthew,  219 

Hales,  ]ohn,  124 

Halifax,   160 

Hamilton,   John      See   Si    Andrews, 

Archbishop  o) 

Hammond    Mr    and  Mrs,  23-24 
Hanse  League,  63,  68 
Harrington,   150 
Harris,  Walter,  224 
Harrison,  224 
Harthb    Samuel,  220 
Hatfield,  Chase,  148 
Hangs,  the,  72 
Heming,    Nicholas,    134,    135 

(quoted) 

Henry  of  Ghent,  quoted,  36 
— of  Langenstem,  quoted,  38,  43 
Herberts,  the,  120,  125 
Hmde,  258 
Hipler,  79,  250 
Hobbes,  23 

Hochstetters,  the,  72,  79,  249 
Holland,   15,   wars  and  commercial 

rivalry  of  England  with,  14,  207, 

209,  222,  266,  religious  develop- 


INDEX 


275 


ments  in  17,  175,  189,  economic 
progress  of,  17,  170,  175,  180 
192,  261,  controversy  in,  about 
usury,  110,  198,  middle  classes 
in,  173,  175,  emigration  of  Dis- 
senters to,  259.  See  also  Dutch 
and  Low  Countries 

Holland,  Lord,  197 

Hooker,  Richard,   141,  145,   195 

Hospitals,  123,  218,  loans  by,  53, 
247 

Hostiensis,  135,  249 

Houblon,  James  and  John,  209 

House  of  Commons,  123,  152,  159, 
219 

— of  Convocation,  137 

Huguenots,  209 

Humanists,  72,  97,  100,  217 

Hungary,  60,  72 

Hutten,  79,  250 

Imhofs,  the,  72 

Independents,  99,  176,  178,  182, 
209 

Indians,  American,  114,  157 

Indifferentism,  23,  24,   159,  229 

Indixidualism,  rise  of,  17,  20,  27, 
61,  68,  73,  121,  139,  142,  146, 
149-163,  189,  196,  208,  210,  211, 
217,  261,  deduction  of,  from 
teaching  of  reformers,  75-76,  81, 
99-100,  188-9  See  also  under 
Pui  itantsm 

Industrial   Revolution,  24,   163 

Innocent  IV,  33,  45,  240 

Intcresse,  43,  44,  85 

Interest,  rate  of,  105,  108,  131,  138, 
153,  267,  "pure,"  43,  true  and 
unfeigned,  not  usury,  249.  See 
also  Intercssc  and  Usury 

Ireland,  192,  224,  269,  Church  of, 
137 

Ireton,  214 

Iron    industry,    16&,    183,    210,    269 

Italy,  16,  53,  67,  medieval  capital- 
ism in,  30,  76,  77-78,  261;  wage- 
earners  in,  30,  40,  238,  financiers 
of,  33,  46,  68,  117,  canonists  of, 
S3,  economic  position  of,  62-63, 
64,  65,  192.  See  also  Florence 
and  Venice 

Jacquerte,  56 

Jewel,  Bishop,  74,  133 

Jews,  39,  207 

John  XXII,  bull  of.  5$ 


John  of  Salisbury,  quoted,  27,  29, 
238 

Joint-stock  enterprise,  outburst  of, 
150 

Jones,  Rev    David,  204 

Journeymen       See     Wage-earners 

Justices  in  Eyre,   51 
—of    Assize,    147 
— of  the  Peace,  usurers  dealt  with 
by,  140,  143,  regulation  of  mar- 
kets and  of  wages  by,  148,   clos* 
ing  of  public-houses  by,  181-182; 
administration   of   poor   laws   by, 
196     218-219,    administration   of 
orders  against  enclosures  by,  147, 
211 

Keane,  Robert,  112-114 
Ket,  123,  248 
Keynes,  J    M  ,  208,  235 
Kidderminster,  172,  183 
King's  Lynn,  247,  254 
Knewstub,  179,  262 
Knox,  John,  16,  24,  101,  104  (quot- 
ed), 111,  177 

Lancashire,  Puritanism  in,  169,  178, 
267  See  also  Bury 

Land,  16,  118-28,  purchase  of,  by 
nouveaux  riches,  and  speculation 
in,  78,  120-1,  123-4,  150,  173, 
?13,  mortgaging  of,  92,  144.  See 
a'so  Enclosures,  Landlords,  P as- 
tute farming,  Property,  Rent- 
charge,  Rents 

Landlords,  oppressions  of,  50,  120, 
13^,  140,  143,  147,  186,  196, 
198  24S,  ecclesiastical,  manage- 
ment of  estates  by,  57,  120,  123. 
See  also  Peasants  and  Rents 

Lanfranc,  23 

Langland,   24,   216 

Lateran  Councils,  47,  53 

Latimer,  16,  24,  74,  121,  125,  211, 
213,  217,  227,  235 

Laud,  16,  24,  100,  116,  145-9,  159, 
171,  175,  177,  196,  197,  211,  256 

Laurentius  de  Rudolfts,  16,  238 

Law,  canon,  16,  141 ;  rules  of,  as  to 
ubury,    17,    39-54,    84-85,    serf** 
dom    recognized   by,    56-57;    dis- 
credit of,  60,  61,  123,  136,  158;  „ 
continued     appeal     to,     74,     77, 
130-9,    251-2;    compatibility    o! 
exchange  business  with,  73.    See 
also  Canoijijts 


276 


INDEX 


— ,  civil,  136-7 

— .common,  136,  138,  158 

—,  natural,  41,  59,  152-3,  162,  215, 

228 

Law,  John,  210 
— ,  William,  161 
Lay  ton,  Dr  ,  136 
Leach,  A    F,  122 
Leadam,  125 
Lease-mongers,  123 
Lee,  Joseph,  quoted,  215 
Leeds,  169 

Leicester,  160,  213,  214 
Leonard,  Miss,  148 
Levellers,  24,  176,  212,  261 
Lever,  74,  121,  123,  133 
Linen  industry,  122 
Lisbon,  72,  77,  79 
Loans,  charitable,  53,  132,  140,  218, 

247,  public,     indemnification     of 
subscribers     to,     152       See     also 
Interest   and    Vsitiy 

Locke,  14,  (quoted),  152,  160,  207, 
214 

Lollards,  50 

Lombard  bankers,  33,  51 

London,  30,  51,  54,  120,  218, 
growth  of  money-maiket  in,  69, 
117,  150,  Nonconformity  in,  93, 
168,  169,  170,  178,  202,  209, 
fire  of,  170,  183,  bishop  of,  33, 
53,  138,  239 

Lotteries,  110,  252 

Low  Countuei,,  65,  66,  67,  70,  192, 
early  capitalism  in,  22,  29,  76, 
239,  261,  wage-earners  m,  30, 
40,  239,  Mont*  de  Piete  in,  53, 

248,  religious   tolerance  m,    171 
See  also  Antwerp  and  PI  oil  and 

Luchaire,  A  ,  33 

Luther,    16,   24,   38,    72-91,   92,    93, 

95,  102,  200,  220,  244 
Lyndwood,    54 
Lyons,  69,   70,   105     Poor  Men  of, 

24,  Council  of,  47 

Machiavelli,  14,  73,  156,  261 

Maidstone,   171 

Maitland,  136 

Major,  95 

Malynes,  G.,  151 

Mandeville,  161    (quoted),  258 

Manning,  B    L  ,  24 

Marx,  Karl,  39,  99,  223 

Massachusetts,  112,  198 

Melanchthon,  74,  82,  95,  135 


Mendicant  oiders,  83 

Mercantilism,  34,  73,  197,  208 

Merchant  Adventures,  63 

Merchants      See   Traders 

Merchet,  126 

Meutmgs,  the,  72,  249 

Middle  classes,  rise  of,  15,  77,  78, 
84,  98,  150,  173,  195,  223,  Cal- 
vinism and  Puritanism  among, 
98,  100,  158,  108-175,  17S-6, 
192,  221.  261,  qualities  of,  98, 
173,  175,  191-2  humblei,  atti- 
tude of,  to  using  commercialism, 
139-40,  economic  position  of, 
172-3,  202,  260 

Middlemen      See    Traders 

Mills,  James,  202 

Milton,   192 

Mines  of  New  World,  64,  of  Eu- 
rope 63-64,  69,  72,  capitalism  in 
working  of,  bS,  150 

Monarch},  pateinal,  17^,  193,  195, 
196-7,  210,  264  See  also  C/iarlcs 
I  and  Tudor rs 

Monasteries,  loans  b>  ,  S^,  247  re- 
lief of  beggars  by,  83,  100,  221; 
dissolution  of,  119-21,  123,  253, 
254 

Mone>lendcis  See  I  nit  test,  Loans 
(pnhlic),  Usury 

Mone\  -market  See  Exchanges, 
Financier,  and  under  London 

Monopolies      See    Patents 

Monopolists,  denimu.it ions  of,  40, 
73-4,  79,  83,  86,  10S,  184 

Montesquieu,  173 

Motifs  de  Ptete,  44    53,  248,  265 

Mooie.  John,  213,  215 

More,  Sn   Thomas,  67,   119 

Mosse,  Miles,  134,  135,  137 
(quoted) 

Mullms,  Archdeacon,  255 


Nationalism,   63,   70 
Netherlands     See  Low  Countries 
New  England,  Calvinism  m,  111-15, 

189,  198 

New  Model  Army,  182 
Nicholas  III,  33 
Nonconformists         See      Chwches 

(Noncomfonmst) ,     Independents, 

Presbytenamsm,      Puritanism, 

Quakers,  Tolerance 
Norfolk,  144,  16& 


INDEX 


277 


North,  Sir  Dudley,  quoted,  208 
Notre-Dame,  Cathedral  of,  33,  240 
Nhrnberg,  77,  97 

O'Brien,  G  ,  44  (cited) 
(Ecolampadius,  74,  94,  101 
Oresme,  Nicholas,  16,  238 
Owen,  Robert,  226 
Oziander,  75 

Paget,  124 

Paley,  23$ 

Pallavicmo,  1  51 

Papacy,   avarice   and   corruption   of, 

33,   77,  80-3,   83,  97,   98,   finan- 
cial  relations  of,  33,  45,  243 
Papillon,  Thomas    209 
Papists,   unaptness  of,  for  business, 

172,  charity  of,  194,  220,  265 

265 
Pans,   30,    69,    73,    105,    109,    240, 

bishop  of,  33,  240 
Parish,  loans  by,  53,  132,  247,  or- 

gam/alion  of  132,  257 
Parker,  Bishop,  140 
Parliament,   Level  lei  b'    demands    for 

reform  of,  212 

Parliament,  Barebones,  182,  205 
— ,  Long,  149,   159,  197,  212,  213 
"Parliaments,"  of  wage-earners,  30, 

239 
Partnership,   profits   of,   ld\\ful,   43, 

242,   fictitious    49,  243 
Pasture  farming,  117,  118,  119,  120, 

122,    124,    147,    1S1        bee    also 

EncloMii  rv 

Patents,  190,  197,  264 
Pawnshops  public,  140 
Peasants,  associations  among,  31  , 

harshness  of  lot  of,  "56,  levolts  of, 

56,  57,    65,    120,    12S-4,    212-13, 
248,   revolts  of,  in  Geimany,  56, 

57,  74,  75,   79,  82,  83,  119,  124, 
248,   emancipation  of,  from  serf- 
dom,   56,   57,   64,    78,    117,    126, 
comparison  of,  with  peasantry  of 
France  and  Germany,  57,  78,  117, 
129,   calling  of,  piaised,  82     See 
also  Jacquctn    and   Landlords 

Peckham,  Archbishop,  33 

Pecock,    Bishop,    50,    54,    89,    244, 

248 

Penn,  William,  159 
Pennsylvania,  198 
Pepper,  69 


Pepys,  170 

Petty,  Sir  William,  171,  207,  209 
(quoted) 

Piccarda,  23 

Pilgrimage  of  Grace,  121 

Pirenne,  Prof  ,  68,  239 

Political  Arithmetic,  17,  157,  160 
170,  208  See  also  Economic 
Science 

Pollexfen,  Sn   Henry,  224 

Ponet,  74,  121 

Poor,  relief  of,  74,  83,  101,  121, 
123,  132,  138,  163,  198,  invest- 
ment of  monev  ioi  benefit  of, 
110,  154,  252,  legislation  re  re- 
lief of.  111,  217-18  219-20,  225, 
268,  269,  administration  of  laws 
for  relief  of,  143,  148,  196,  218; 
right  of,  to  relief,  219,  225, 
relief  to,  to  be  deterrent,  225, 
268-9,  able-bodied,  employment 
of,  143,  217-18,  219,  220,  225, 
268  See  aKo  Alw&givmg,  Pov- 
ctty,  Valiancy 

—  Law  Commissioners,  225,  269 

—  Men  of  Lyons,  24 
Poitug.il,   60,   65,   66,   68,   69,   76 
Povert} ,   attitude   of  Swics   reform- 

eis  to,  93,  100-1,  115,  attitude 
to,  in  eighteenth  century,  160-1; 
attitude  of  Puritans  to,  193-4, 
210-12,  216-226,  medieval  atti- 
tude to,  216-268,  attitude  of 
Qiuikeis  to,  226,  causes  of,  217, 
219-20,220-22,224,269  See  also 
Poor 

Predestination,  96.  99 

Presbytenamsm,  165,  177-78,  180-1, 
262  263  See  also  Pwtlanisn 

Pi  esb>  terians  169,  172,  209,  strug- 
gle between  Independents  and, 
99,  176,  178 

Prices,  ii^e  in,  16,  65,  69,  74,  118, 
126,  150,  153,  just,  doctrine  with 
regard  to,  22,  39,  42,  74,  85, 
131,  133,  180,  184,  187,  203, 
223,  240,  242,  262,  269,  control 
of,  43,  103,  105,  107,  108,  112- 
14,  122,  143,  148,  217-18,  264; 
opposition  to  control  of,  152,  195, 
259-60  See  also  Bargaining 

Privy  Council,  activities  of,  142-4, 
147-8,  196-7,  265 

Production,  206,  267,  208 


278  INDEX 

Profits,  medieval  doctrine  as  to,  35, 
37-8,  43,  93,  attempted  limita- 
tion of,  in  New  England,  111-14 
See  also  Traders 

Property,  theories  with  regard  to, 
35,  91,  125-28,  160,  214,  216, 
217-18 

Prophesy  ings,  167 

Public-houses,  closing  of,  182 

Puritanism,  164-226,  quarrel  be- 
tween monarchy  and,  14,  177, 
193,  195-7,  263,  medieval,  24, 
discipline  of,  100,  111-4,  158, 
177-82,  195,  261,  theology  of, 
100,  189-91,  connection  of  indi- 
vidualism with,  99-100,  111,  176, 
177,  182,  188,  191-8,  210,  211, 
221,225,  226,  261,  divergent  ele- 
ments in,  155,  176-7,261,  sancti- 
fication  of  business  life  by,  165, 
167,  191,  194,  199-211,  225,  geo- 
graphical distribution  of,  168-9; 
connection  of,  with  capitalism, 
176,  268.  See  also  Galvanism, 
Middle  classes,  New  England, 
Poverty,  Presbytcrtamsm,  Usury 

Quakers,  24,  226,  269 

Quarter   Sessions       See  Justices    oj 

the  Peace 
Quicksilver,  72 

Rabelais,  71 

Rationalism,  medieval,  24 

Reformation,  relation  of,  to  changes 
in  social  theory,  21,  24-5,  61-2, 
74,  74-7,  80-4,  121,  132,  133-7 

Regensburg,  77,  187 

Religion,  sphere  of,  all-embracing, 
12,  15-17,  20,  23-4,  24-38,  58-9, 
74-7,  81,  86-7,  88,  127,  129-49, 
154-5,  184,  186-8,  228,  229, 
230-1,  234  (see  also  under  Trad- 
ers) ;  economic  and  social  activ- 
ities excluded  from  province  of, 
12-13,  13-19,  22-3,  81-2,  86-90, 
149,  150-63,  184,  188,  198,  211, 
227,  228-235,  wars  of,  14,  105 
See  also  Asceticism,  Galvanism, 
Indifferentism,  Prei>  bytenanism, 
Purttantsm,  Reformation,  Toler- 
ance 

Rent-charge,  considered  lawful,  44, 
as,  154,  179,  181,  242 


Rents,  control  of,  at  Geneva,  103; 
raising  of,  105,  120,  125,  131; 
Baxter's  teaching  as  to,  186 

Rhode  Island,  198 

Riches,  medieval  attitude  to,  35-6, 
36,  54,  233,  248,  attitude  of  Cal- 
vimsts  and  Puritans  to,  93,  115, 
191,  198-9,  221-2,  modern  atti- 
tude to,  231-35.  See  also  Finan- 
ciers and  Traders 

Ridley,  Thomas,  quoted,  158 

Ripon,  52 

Rome,  corruption  and  avarice  at, 
32-33,  77,  81,  83,  98 

Root  and  Branch  Petition,  259 

Rotenburg,  77 

Rouen,  69 

Rousseau,  240 

Royal  African  Co  ,  207,  266 

St    Ambrose,  216 

St   Andrews,  111,  archbishop  of,  50 

St  Antonio,  16,  22,  35,  42,  80,  187, 
238,  241,  242 

St   Augustine,  48 

St    Bernard,  33 

St    Francis,  23,  55 

St.  Johns,  the,  120,  253 

St   Leon,  Martin,  31,  239,  240 

St    Raymond,  48,  131 

St  Thomas,  22,  25,  34,  36,  38,  41, 
42,  58,  130,  187,  216,  249 

Salerno,  archbishop  of,  48 

Salisbury,  bishop  of,  133,  mayor  of, 
181 

Sanderson,  Bishop,  159 

Sandwich,  171 

Sandys,  Bishop,  74,  133 

Sdy,  J    B,  11 

Saye  and  Sele,  Lord,  148,  257 

Schoolmen,  16,  22,  25,  34-39,  42-3, 
73,  75,  127,  130,  133,  135,  155, 
187  See  also  St  Antomo  and 
St  Thomas 

Schools,  confiscation  of  endowments 
of,  122-3,  254,  establishment  of, 
by  Church,  163  See  also  Educa- 
tion 

Schulze-Gaevernitz,  176 

Scotland,  100,  111,  189,  Commis- 
sioners from,  178 

Scriveners,  150 

Self-interest,  of  individual,  harmony 
of  needs  of  society  with,  19,  28- 
29,  152,  161,  162-3,  204,  215- 
217,  227.  See  also  Individualism 


Senior,  Nassau,  225,  269 

Serfdom,  55-7,  attitude  of  Church 
to,  27,  56-8  See  also  Peasants. 

Serfs,  runaway,  126,  253  See  also 
Peasants 

Seville,  69,  116 

Shaftesbury,  Ecirl  of,  207 

Shaw,  W   A  ,  178 

Sheep-grazing      See  Pasture  j arming 

Sheldon,  Dr    Gilbert,  257 

Sidney,  Sir  Philip,  120 

Sigismund,  Emperor,  Refoimation 
of,  79,  240 

Silver,  of  America,  64,  68,  116,  of 
Europe,  72 

Sion,  Monastery  of,  120 

Slave- trade,  1S7 

Smiles,  Samuel,  210 

Smith,  Adam,  38,  162,  210,  240 

— ,  Rev    Henry,   179,  262 

— ,  Sir  Thomas,    136 

Smiths,  of  London,   52,   239,   246 

Soap,  monopoly  of,  197,  264 

Social  Democratic  movement,  182 

Society,  functional  theory  of,  19, 
27-9,  83,  87,  127,  144-6,  146, 
146-7,  160,  162,  211,  modern 
conception  of,  19,  27,  160,  162 

Somerset,  Duke  of,   102,  126,  254 

South  Sea  Rubble,  162 

Spam,  65,  66,  70,  72,  76,  dealers 
of,  on  Antwerp  Bouise,  73 

Speculation      See  r.nqio\'\ii!> 

Speenhamland,   219 

Spices,  trade  in,  08,  69,  72,  77 

Spinola,  151 

Spurriers,  of  London,  52,  246 

Starkey,  27,   119,  238 

State,  relation  between  Church  and, 
13-17,  23-4,  25,  65,  81-2,  90-1, 
109,  136  141-2,  145-6,  146-7, 
149,  2 2 8-9, Locke's  conception  of, 
14  (quoted),  152,  160,  unitary, 
soveteignty  of,  228,  239,  Distrib- 
utive, 83,  129 

Steelc,  Richard,  200,  202,  202-4, 
208,  221 

Step-lords,  125 

Stockwood,   Rev    J  ,  quoted,  220 

Strafford,  Earl  of,  175,  177,  196 

Strassburg,  69 

Stubbes,  Philip,   179 

Summa,  22,  25,  34,  183.  See  also 
Schoolmen 

Swift,  Dean,  172 


INDEX  279 

Switzerland,  Reformation  in,  91-110, 
121,  220,  bourgeoisie  in,  98,  107, 
173 

Synods,  French,  109-10 

Taunton,  169 

Taylor,  Jeremy,   137    (quoted),   159 

Temple,  Sir  William,  171 

Tenures,  military,  abolition  of,  213 

Textile  workers,  of  Elanders  and 
Italy,  30,  239,  of  Pans,  239. 
*or  England  see  under  Cloth  in- 
dustry 

Tobacco,  111 

Toleiance,  lebgious,  100,  104,  149, 
182,  commercially  advantageous, 
17,  164,  170-1 

Tories,  distrust  of  commercial  classes 
by  172 

Torrens,    R  ,    11 

Townsend,  Rev    J  ,  258 

Trade,  flourishing  of,  under  religious 
tolerance,  17,  164,  170-1,  free 
exercise  of,  152,  foreign,  increase 
in,  117,  ISO,  balance  of,  205,  208 

Trade  unionism,  30,  23° 

Traders,  medieval  attitude  to,  22-3, 
28,  35,  36-8,  30,  82,  relations 
between  craftsmen  and,  30,  117, 
118,  147-8,  196,  264,  sanctifica- 
tion  of  occupation  of,  36-7,  92, 
95-6,  96,  97,  98,  101,  165-6,  167, 
191,  194,  109-210,  211,  226, 
frauds  and  extoition  of  50,  93, 
104,  110,  122,  131,  133-4,  245, 
253,  Luther's  attitude  to,  82; 
growth  of  power  of,  117,  118, 
purchase  of  land  by,  120,  173; 
break-down  of  State  control  of, 
152,  196  See  also  Bai  gaining, 
Prices,  Pi o fits 

Ti avers,  W  ,  177 

Trocltsch,  Prof,  81,  176,  260 

Tucker,  Dean,  17,  162,  164  (quoted), 
258 

Tudors,  social  policy  of,  140-145, 
195,  217-18,  221,  224 

Turgot,  240 

Turks,  64 

Tyndale,  254,  268 

Tyrol,  64,  69,  72 

Udall,  J,  258 

Ulm,  77 

Unwm,  Prof.,  148 

Usher,  R.  G,  168 

Usury,  controversy  on,  16,  73,  74, 


INDEX 


132-40,  151,  1S3-5;  teaching  of 
medieval  Church  on,  22,  39-41, 
43-54,  practicing  of,  on  a  large 
scale,  in  Middle  Ages,  33,  45-6, 
150,  restitution  of  profits  of,  33, 
46-7,  47,  49,  enforcement  of  pro- 
hibition of,  39,  46-52,  89,  105, 
106,  108,  111,  137-8,  140,  144, 
159, 197,  198, 243-4,  244-5,  255, 
prevalence  of  41,  129-30,  popular 
denunciations  of,  41,  74,  119,  123, 
130,  annuities,  compensation  for 
loss,  profits  of  partnership  and 
rent-charges  not  regarded  as,  43, 
44,  85,  154,  180-1,  241-2,  eccle- 
siastical legislation  as  to,  47,  51, 
54,  devices  for  concealment  of, 
47,  48,  52,  243,  secular  legisla- 
tion as  to,  51-2,  131,  136,  153, 
159,  attitude  of  reformers  to,  in 
Germany,  74,  75,  84,  85,  89;  in 
Switzerland,  74,  75,  92,  93-6, 
103,  104-9,  154,  179,  180,  in 
France,  110,  252,  meaning  of 
term,  130-1,  136-7,  154,  disap- 
pears from  episcopal  charges,  1 62 , 
Puritan  attitude  to,  174,  177, 
179-80,  181,  185,  187,  192-3, 
198-9,  204,  209,  223,  262,  263, 
264  See  also  Clergy,  Interest, 
Loans 

Utilitarianism,  202,  225 
Utrecht,  University  of,  198 

Vagrancy,  measures  for  suppression 
of,  83,  143,  181,  217-8,  218,  220, 
223-4,  225,  increase  of,  218,  220. 
See  also  Almsgtvtng  and  Poor 

Value,  theories  of,  38,  41-2 

Venezuela,  72 

Venice,  64,  65,  68,  69,  78,  105,  261 

Vienne,  Council  of,  47 

Villeinage.    See  Serfdom 

Virtues,  economic,  applauding  of, 
by  Caivmists  and  Puritans,  93, 
97,  98,  101,  189-210,  225-6,  226 

Vitry,  Jacques  de,  248 

Vives,  100,  217 

Voltaire,  173 

Wadsworth,  A  P  ,  267 

Wage-earners,  small  number  of,  30, 
40,  118,  129,  172,  222,  239;  or- 
ganizations  of,  30,  attitude  of 
economists  to,  222-24.  See  also 
Wages 


Wages,  withholding  of,  50,  185, 
245,  regulation  of,  112,  148,  195, 
196,  240,  244,  payment  of,  in 
truck,  131,  148,  196,  economists' 
views  on  the  subject  of,  222-5, 
225  See  also  Wage-earners 

Wallas,  Graham,   19 

Wamba,  81 

Warburton,  162 

Ward,  Sir  Patience,  209 

Warwick,  Earl  of,  124 

Warwickshire,  119,  267 

Wa^herne,  120 

Wealth     See  Production  and  Riches 

Weber,  Max,  176,  260-1,  262,  265 

Welsers,  the,  72,  79,  249 

Wentworth,   148 

We?ley,  161 

Westminster  Assembly.  17,  178,  181 

Whalley,  ecclesiastical  court  of,  52 

Whalley,  Major-General,  214,  267 

Whigs,  169,  210 

Whitby,  Abbey,  120 

Whole  Duty  of  Man,  The,  162 

Widows  and  orphans,  usury  for  ben- 
efit of,  154,  193 

Wi'cox,  Thomas,  138 

Williams,  Roger,  112 

WiNon,  Thomas,  133,  134,  136,  152, 
195,  263 

Wiltshire,  182,  197 

Wmstanley,  Gerrard,  99  (quoted), 
212 

Witt,  John  de,  171 

Wolsey,  119,  126 

Wood,  H    G  ,  262 

Woodrow,  Rev    Robert,  quoted,  198 

Woollen  industry  See  Cloth  indus- 
try 

Worcester,  Priory  of,  44 

Workhouses,  220,   224,  225,  269 

Works,  good,  88,  96,  98,  199,  201, 
221,  265 

Wychf,  23,  29  (quoted),  31,  41 
(quoted),  42,  239 

Yarranton,  A  ,  210 
Yeomanry,  56,  168 
York.  Province  of    137,  144 
Yorke,  Sir  John,  120 
Yorkshire,  121,  138,  169 
Young,  Arthur,  224 
Younge,  R  ,  quoted,  221 

Ztirich,  92,  101,  103 
Zwingli,  74,  92,  101,  103 


The    Mentor    Philosophers 

The  entire  range  of  Western  speculative  thinking  from 
the  Middle  Ages  to  modern  times  is  presented  in  this 
series  of  six  volumes  which  are  unique  in  the  low-priced 
field  Each  book  contains  the  basic  writings  of  the 
leading  philosophers  of  each  age,  with  introductions 
and  interpretive  commentary  by  noted  authorities 
"A  very  important  and  interesting  series  " 

— Gilbert  Highet 

75    Cents    Each 

THE  AGE  OF  BELIEF  :  The  Medieval  Philosophers 

Edited  by  Anne  Premantle  (  #MT4-63)  "A  well-chosen 
sampler  of  the  writings  of  the  great  philosophers  of 
the  fifth  to  15th  centuries." 

— Saturday  Review  Syndicate 

THE  AGE  OF  ADVENTURE  :  The  Renaissance  Philosophers 

Edited  by  Giorgio  de  Santillana  ( -#  MT437  )  .  "That 
most  romantic,  feitile  and  productive  period  of  mod- 
ern civilization — the  Renaissance  " 

— The   Pioneer    (India) 

THE  AGE  OF  REASON:  The  17th  Century  Philosophers 

Edited  by  Stuart  Hampshire  (#MT367).  "The  New- 
American  Library  has  earned  the  gratitude  of  tens  of 
thousands  .  .  .  bv  providing  them  with  such  intellec- 
tual fare  at  so  cheap  a  price." 

—  ShanLar^s    Weekly    (India) 

THE  AGE  OF  ENLIGHTENMENT: 

The  18th  Century  Philosophers 

Edited  by  Isaiah  Berlin  (#MT473)  "Mr.  Berlin  .  .  . 
has  one  of  the  liveliest  and  most  stimulating  minds 
among  contemporary  philo^ophei  s  " 

— TV    Y    Herald  Tribune 

THE  AGE  OF  IDEOLOGY:  The  19th  Century  Philosophers 

Edited  br  Henry  D  Aiken  (#MT421).  "...  a 
rounded  and  sympathetic  presentation  of  the  19th  cen- 
tury .  .  .  most  distinct  intellectual  contribution  .  .  .** 

—The  New  York  Times 

THE  AGE  OF  ANALYSIS:  20th  Century  Philosophers 

Edited  by  Morton  White  (#MT353).    "No  other  book 

remotely  rivals  this  as  the  best  available  introduction 

,  to   20th   century   philosophy.5' — N.    Y.   Herald    Tribune 


MENTOR  Books  on  International  Affairs 

Russia  and  America:  Dangers  and  Prospects  by  Henry  L. 
Roberta  A  penetrating  analysis  of  the  relations  between  the 
two  most  powerful  nations,  in  an  atmosphere  of  global  ten- 
sions created  by  atomic  weapons.  (#MDl82 


Russia  (revised)  by  Bernard  Pares.  An  authoritative  study  of 
the  background  of  the  most  controversial  country  in  the 
world  today  (#MP398  —  60<J) 

The  Dynamics  of  Soviet  Society  by  W.  W.  Rostow  and 
others,  A  synthesis  and  interpretation  of  the  political,  eco- 
nomic, and  social  structures  of  Soviet  Russia. 

(#MP406—  600  ) 

The  Nature  of  the  Non-  Western  World  by  Vera  Michele? 
Dean.  An  expert  on  world  affairs  probes  the  beliefs,  tradi- 
tions, and  emotions  that  motivate  the  billion  and  a  half  peo- 
ple of  non-Western  nations.  (#MP422  —  60<J) 

Gandhi:  His  Life  and  Message  for  the  World  by  Louis 
Fischer.  The  life  story  of  one  of  the  greatest  religious  and 
political  leaders  of  our  time  gives  insight  into  India's  pivotal 
place  in  world  affairs.  (#MP390  —  60(J) 

Islam  in  Modern  History  by  Wilfred  Cantwell  Smith.  A 
noted  scholar  discusses  the  impact  of  Mohammedanism  on 
Middle  Eastern  political  life  today.  (#MD268  —  50(J) 

The  True  Believer  by  Eric  Hoffer.  A  provocative  analysts  of 
the  nature  of  mass  movements  and  the  fanatics  who  give 
them  power.  (#MP434  —  600) 

American  Diplomacy:  1900-1950  by  George  F.  Kennan.  A 
trenchant  appraisal  of  U.  S.  foreign  relations  by  a  distin- 
guished diplomat.  (#MP360  —  60lJ) 

To  OUR  READERS:  If  your  dealer  does  not  have  the  SIGNET 
and  MENTOR  books  you  want,  you  may  order  them  by  mail  enr 
closing  the  list  price  plus  5<J  a  copy  to  cover  mailing.  If  you 
would  like  our  free  catalog,  please  request  it  by  postcard.  The 
New  America*!  Library  of  World  Literature,  Inc.,  P.  O.  Box 


ew     meca*!       rary  o 


How  has  religion  affected 
social  and  economic  practices? 

In  this  world-famous  book,  a  leading  modern  econo- 
mist discusses  this  vital  question  as  he  traces  the 
influence  of  religious  thought  on  social  and  economic 
development  since  the  Middle  Ages  and  explains  the 
relationship  between  religion  today  and  our  modern 
capitalistic  system. 

The  late  R.  H.  TAWNEY,  renowned  English  economist, 
was  born  in  India  in  1880.  He  studied  at  Rugby  and 
at  Balliol  College,  Oxford,  taught  at  Glasgow  and 
Oxford  universities,  and  was  Professor  Emeritus  of 
Economic  History  at  the  University  of  London.  A  mem- 
ber of  the  British  Labour  Party  for  over  fifty  years, 
he  served  on  many  public  bodies  and  as  economic 
advisor  to  the  British  Embassy  in  Washington.  Inter- 
nationally acclaimed,  Religion  and  the  Rise  of  Capi- 
talism was  published  in  hardcover  by  Harcourt, 
Brace  &  Co. 


26 


01