Skip to main content

Full text of "Report"

See other formats


Digitized  by  tine  Internet  Arciiive 

in  2010  witii  funding  from 

Tine  Law  Foundation  of  Ontario  &  tine  Ontario  Council  of  University  Libraries 


http://www.archive.org/details/reporttaxation01onta 


3  9007  0252  4884  0 


y 


Date  Due 


THE  ( 
COIN/ir 


ION 


REPOR' 


Printed  and  Published  by 
FRANK  FOGG 
Queen's  Printer 
Price  $15  per  set 


THE  ONTARIO 
COMMITTEE  ON  TAXATION 

VOLUME  I 

APPROACH,  BACKGROUND 
AND  CONCLUSIONS 


To  His  Honour 

The  Honourable  W.  Earle  Rowe,  P.C.,  LL.D.,  D.Sc.  Soc. 

Lieutenant  Governor  of  Ontario 

May  it  please  Your  Honour 

We,  the  commissioners  of  The  Ontario  Committee  on  Taxation  appointed 
under  The  Public  Inquiries  Act  by  Order-in-Council  OC-5 57/63,  dated  the  26th 
day  of  February,  1963,  to  inquire  into  and  report  upon  the  taxation  and  revenue 
system  of  the  Province  of  Ontario  and  its  municipalities  and  school  boards  within 
the  terms  set  forth  in  that  Order-in-Council,  beg  to  submit  the  accompanying 
Report. 


Chairman 


(3^C^ 


f\.  Cj^/uu^    An^yj, 


August  30,  1967 
Toronto, 


ONTARIO 
EXECUTIVE  COUNCIL  OFFICE 

Copy  of  an  Order-in-Council  approved  by  His  Honour  the  Lieutenant  Governor, 
dated  the  26th  day  of  February,  A.D.  1963. 

Upon  the  recommendation  of  the  Honourable  the  Prime  Minister,  the  Com- 
mittee of  Council  advise  that  pursuant  to  the  provisions  of  The  Public  Inquiries  Act, 
R.S.O.  1960,  Chapter  323,  and  effective  from  November  21,  1962,  a  commission 
be  issued  appointing: 

Lancelot  J.  Smith,  F.C.A.,  Toronto, 
Eric  Hardy,  Toronto, 

Dr.  R.  Craig  Mclvor,  Hamilton, 

Carl  Pollock,  Kitchener,  and 

R.  Bredin  Stapells,  Q.C.       Toronto, 

as  commissioners,  designating  them  as  The  Ontario  Committee  on  Taxation,  and 
naming  the  said  Lancelot  J.  Smith  as  chairman  thereof, 

(a)  to  inquire  into  and  report  upon  the  taxation  and  revenue  system  of  the 
Province  of  Ontario  and  its  municipalities  and  school  boards  in  relation 
to  their  expenditures,  the  tax  and  revenue  sources  available  to  them,  their 
debts  and  other  financial  obhgations,  with  a  view  to  determining  whether, 
within  the  constitutional  limitations  existing  and  having  regard  to  present 
and  potential  financial  requirements,  such  tax  and  revenue  system  is  as 
simple,  clear,  equitable,  efficient,  adequate  and  as  conducive  to  the  sound 
growth  of  the  Province  as  can  be  devised, 

(b)  in  connection  therewith,  to  inquire  into  such  other  matters  as  the  com- 
missioners shall  deem  advisable, 

(c)  to  co-operate  with  the  Royal  Commission  on  Taxation  and  with  any 
other  bodies  of  inquiry  appointed  by  other  Provincial  Governments,  and 

(d)  after  due  study  and  consideration,  to  make  such  recommendations  in 
accordance  with  the  objectives  and  terms  set  out  herein  as  the  commis- 
sioners see  fit  to  the  Prime  Minister  and  the  Executive  Council  of  Ontario. 

The  Committee  further  advise  that  pursuant  to  tlie  said  Act  the  said  commis- 
sioners shall  have  the  power  of  summoning  any  person  and  requiring  him  to  give 
evidence  on  oath  and  to  produce  such  documents  and  things  as  the  commissioners 
deem  requisite  for  the  full  investigation  of  the  matters  into  which  they  are 
appointed  to  examine; 

And  the  Committee  further  advise  that  all  Government  departments,  boards, 
agencies  and  committees  shall  assist,  to  the  fullest  extent,  the  said  The  Ontario 
Committee  on  Taxation  which,  in  order  to  carry  out  its  duties  and  functions,  shall 
have  the  power  and  authority  to  engage  such  counsel,  staff  and  technical  advisers 
as  it  deems  proper. 

Certified, 

J.  J.  Young, 

Clerk,  Executive  Council 

vii 


PROVINCE  OF  ONTARIO 

(Signed)  W.  Earl  Rowe 

ELIZABETH   THE  SECOND,  by  the  Grace  of  God  of  the  United   Kingdom, 

Canada  and  Her  other  Realms  and  Territories, 
Queen,  Head  of  the  Commonwealth,  Defender 
of  the  Faith. 

TO   Lancelot  J.  Smith,  Esquire,  of  the  City  of  Toronto;  Eric  Hardy,  Esquire,  of 
the  City  of  Toronto;  Dr.  R.  Craig  Mclvor,  of  the  City  of  Hamilton;  Carl 
Pollock,  Esquire,  of  the  City  of  Kitchener  and  R.  Bredin  Stapells,  One  of 
Our  Counsel  learned  in  the  Law,  of  the  City  of  Toronto 

GREETING: 
WHEREAS  in  and  by  Chapter  323  of  The  Revised  Statutes  of  Ontario,  1960, 
entided  'The  Public  Inquiries  Act",  it  is  enacted  that  whenever  Our  Lieutenant 
Governor  in  Council  deems  it  expedient  to  cause  inquiry  to  be  made  concerning 
any  matter  connected  with  or  affecting  the  good  government  of  Ontario  or  the 
conduct  of  any  part  of  the  public  business  thereof  or  of  the  administration  of 
justice  therein  and  such  inquiry  is  not  regulated  by  any  special  law,  he  may,  by 
Commission  appoint  one  or  more  persons  to  conduct  such  inquriy  and  may  confer 
the  power  of  summoning  any  person  and  requiring  him  to  give  evidence  on  oath 
and  to  produce  such  documents  and  things  as  the  commissioner  or  commissioners 
deems  requisite  for  the  full  investigation  of  the  matters  into  which  he  or  they  are 
appointed  to  examine; 

AND  WHEREAS  Our  Lieutenant  Governor  in  Council  of  Our  Province  of 
Ontario  deems  it  expedient  to  cause  inquiry  to  be  made  concerning  the  matters 
hereinafter  mentioned: 

NOW  KNOW  Ye  that  We,  having  and  reposing  full  trust  and  confidence  in 
you  the  said  Lancelot  J.  Smith,  Eric  Hardy,  Dr.  R.  Craig  Mclvor,  Carl  PoUock 
and  R.  Bredin  Stapells,  One  of  Our  Counsel  learned  in  the  Law  DO  HEREBY 
APPOINT  you,  effective  November  21st,  1962,  to  be  Our  Commissioners,  desig- 
nating you  as  "The  Ontario  Committee  on  Taxation",  and  naming  you,  the  said 
Lancelot  J.  Smith  to  be  the  Chairman  thereof, 

(a)  to  inquire  into  and  report  upon  the  taxation  and  revenue  system  of  Our 
Province  of  Ontario  and  its  municipalities  and  school  boards  in  relation  to 
their  expenditures,  the  tax  and  revenue  sources  available  to  them,  their  debts 
and  other  financial  obligations,  with  a  view  to  determining  whether,  within  the 
constitutional  limitations  existing  and  having  regard  to  present  and  potential 
financial  requirements,  such  tax  and  revenue  system  is  as  simple,  clear,  equi- 
table, efficient,  adequate  and  as  conducive  to  the  sound  growth  of  Our 
Province  as  can  be  devised, 

ix 


(b)  in  connection  therewith,  to  inquire  into  such  other  matters  as  you  the  said 
commissioners  shall  deem  advisable, 

(c)  to  co-operate  with  the  Royal  Commission  on  Taxation  and  with  any  other 
bodies  of  inquiry  appointed  by  other  Provincial  Governments,  and 

(d)  after  due  study  and  consideration,  to  make  such  recommendations  in  accor- 
dance with  the  objectives  and  terms  set  out  herein  as  you  the  said  commis- 
sioners see  fit  to  Our  Prime  Minister  and  Our  Executive  Council  of  Ontario. 

AND  WE  DO  HEREBY  CONFER  on  you.  Our  said  Commissioners,  the 
power  to  summon  any  person  and  require  him  to  give  evidence  on  oath  and  to 
produce  such  documents  and  things  as  you  Our  said  Commissioners  deem  requisite 
for  the  full  investigation  of  the  matters  into  which  you  are  appointed  to  examine. 

AND  WE  DO  HEREBY  FURTHER  ORDER  that  aU  Our  departments, 
boards,  commissions,  agencies  and  committees  shall  assist  you.  Our  said  Commis- 
sioners, to  the  fullest  extent,  and  that  in  order  to  carry  out  your  duties  and  functions, 
you  shall  have  the  authority  to  engage  such  counsel,  research  and  other  staff  and 
technical  advisers  as  you  deem  proper. 

TO  HAVE,  HOLD  AND  ENJOY  the  said  Office  and  authority  of  Commis- 
sioner for  and  during  the  pleasure  of  Our  Lieutenant  Governor  in  Council  for  Our 
Province  of  Ontario. 

IN  TESTIMONY  WHEREOF  We  have  caused  these  Our  Letters  to  be  made 
Patent,  and  the  Great  Seal  of  Our  Province  of  Ontario  to  be  hereunto  affixed. 

WITNESS:   THE  HONOURABLE  WILLIAM  EARL  ROWE, 

A  Member  of  Our  Privy  Council  for  Canada, 
Doctor  of  Laws,  Doctor  of  Social  Science, 

LIEUTENANT  GOVERNOR  OF  OUR  PROVINCE  OF 
ONTARIO 

at  Our  City  of  Toronto  in  Our  said  Province,  this  second  day  of  May  in  the  year 
of  Our  Lord  one  thousand  nine  hundred  and  sixty-three  and  in  the  twelfth  year  of 

Our  Reign. 

(Signed)  John  Yaremko 

BY  COMMAND 

PROVINCIAL  SECRETARY  AND 

MINISTER  OF  CITIZENSHIP 


Preface 

Upon  our  appointment,  we  undertook  the  most  extensive  inquiry  into  the  taxa- 
tion and  revenue  system  of  the  Province  of  Ontario  and  its  municipahties  and 
school  boards  that  has  ever  been  made.  Our  terms  of  reference  required  us  to 
examine  the  taxes  and  revenue  sources  available  to  both  the  Province  and  its  local 
governments  as  well  as  their  debts  and  other  financial  obligations.  We  were 
directed  to  determine  whether,  within  existing  constitutional  limitations  and  with 
regard  to  not  only  present  but  potential  financial  requirements,  the  tax  and  revenue 
system  is  as  simple,  clear,  equitable,  efficient,  adequate  and  as  conducive  to  the 
sound  growth  of  the  Province  as  can  be  devised.  We  believe  that  this  Report, 
subscribed  to  by  all  of  us  without  dissent,  fulfils  the  responsibility  entrusted  to 
us  in  accordance  with  our  terms  of  reference. 

As  is  customary  with  a  Royal  Commission  of  Inquiry,  we  invited  written  sub- 
missions from  individuals  and  organizations  to  assist  us  in  our  deliberations.  We 
were  gratified  to  receive  briefs  from  one  hundred  and  seven  organizations^  and 
forty-six  individuals,-  representing  almost  every  economic  activity  and  walk  of  Ufe. 

Later  we  held  twenty-four  days  of  hearings  at  which  we  took  the  opportunity 
of  exploring  further  the  views  of  five  individuals  and  the  representatives  of  fifty-six 
organizations  who  had  previously  submitted  briefs.  These  hearings  proved  helpful 
not  only  in  identifying  the  problem  areas  but  also  in  bringing  us  to  the  realization 
of  the  extreme  divergences  of  opinion  concerning  the  revenue  system  and  proposals 
for  its  improvement. 

In  addition  to  public  hearings,  we  received  invaluable  assistance  from  informal 
discussions  with  a  host  of  government,  academic,  professional  and  business  people 
possessing  special  knowledge  of  matters  of  concern  to  us. 

We  instituted  a  broad  but  selective  research  program  in  the  areas  of  our  interest. 
For  convenience  this  work  was  divided  into  studies  of  the  economic  effects  of 
various  tax  and  revenue  sources,  and  studies  of  the  structure  and  operation  of 
available  forms  of  taxes  and  other  means  of  raising  revenue.  While  some  of  this 
work  was  done  by  persons  on  staff,  by  far  the  larger  part  was  entrusted  to  outside 
specialists.  Of  the  many  studies  made  for  the  Committee  by  those  participating  in 
our  research  program,  those  listed  in  Appendix  D  were  considered  of  sufficient 
general  interest  to  warrant  publication.  We  wish  to  make  it  clear  that  while  we 
were  greatly  assisted  by  those  who  participated  in  our  research  program,  the 
responsibility  for  the  views  and  proposals  contained  in  this  Report  is  entirely 
our  own. 

We  did  not  commission  any  studies  on  the  structure  of  the  federal  income  tax 
which  forms  the  base  for  Ontario's  personal  income  tax  and  to  which  Ontario's 


'Names  listed  in  Appendix  A  to  this  Volume. 
-Names  listed  in  Appendix  B  to  this  Volume. 

xi 


corporation  income  tax  conforms.  The  structure  of  income  tax  was  the  subject  of 
a  thorough  examination  by  the  federal  Royal  Commission  on  Taxation  and  we  did 
not  wish  to  duplicate  its  studies  in  view  of  our  other  responsibilities. 

We  have  not  dealt  in  this  Report  with  the  conclusions  and  recommendations 
of  the  federal  Royal  Commission  on  Taxation.  First,  it  was  necessary  for  us  to 
report  on  the  tax  and  revenue  system  as  it  now  is,  rather  than  on  what  it  would  be 
in  the  event  that  the  federal  government  implemented  the  recommendations  of  the 
federal  Commission.  Second,  at  the  time  that  the  Commission  reported,  our  own 
Report  had  progressed  to  such  a  stage  that  to  take  the  federal  findings  into  con- 
sideration would  have  involved  substantial  rewriting.  Finally,  any  worth-while 
appraisal  of  the  implications  for  Ontario  of  the  recommendations  of  the  federal 
Commission  would  have  unduly  delayed  the  presentation  of  our  Report. 

We  were  directed  in  our  terms  of  reference  to  co-operate  with  the  federal  Royal 
Commission  on  Taxation  and  with  any  other  bodies  of  inquiry  appointed  by  other 
provincial  governments.  We  are  most  grateful  for  the  co-operation  freely  extended 
to  us  not  only  by  the  commissioners  and  staff  of  the  federal  Royal  Commission  on 
Taxation  but  also  by  those  of  the  Saskatchewan,  Manitoba,  Quebec,  New  Bruns- 
wick and  Nova  Scotia  bodies  of  inquiry. 

In  Appendix  C  to  this  Volume  we  have  noted  the  names  of  those  who  con- 
tributed to  our  work  as  members  of  staff  and  as  research  consultants  and  study 
authors.  We  are  appreciative  of  the  contribution  made  by  each  of  them.  Not  to 
be  found  in  these  lists,  however,  are  innumerable  officials  and  staff  members  of 
government  departments,  boards,  agencies  and  committees,  at  the  provincial,  local 
and  federal  levels,  who  gave  us  their  utmost  assistance.  For  their  unstinted 
co-operation  we  express  our  grateful  thanks. 

In  acknowledging  the  significant  contribution  made  by  staff,  we  wish  particularly 
to  mention  the  loyalty  and  indefatigable  efforts  of  our  secretary,  Hugh  R.  Hanson, 
and  our  four  directors,  F.  Warren  Hurst,  F.C.A.,  Dr.  J.  Stefan  Dupre,  Dr.  Robert 
M.  Clark,  and  F.  Gerald  Townsend,  C.A.  Their  services  involved  the  sacrifice  of 
much  of  their  personal  life  for  a  long  period. 

We  are  also  indebted  to  all  of  the  universities,  government  departments,  pro- 
fessional firms,  corporations  and  organizations  who  released  members  of  their  staffs 
to  us  at  considerable  inconvenience  to  themselves.  We  extend  our  appreciation  in 
this  regard  especially  to  the  Consumers  Gas  Company  for  Mr.  Hurst,  the  Treasurer 
of  Ontario  for  Mr.  Hanson,  The  University  of  Toronto  for  Professor  Dupre,  The 
University  of  British  Columbia  for  Professor  Clark,  and  the  firm  of  Thorne, 
Mulholland,  Howson  &  McPherson  for  Mr.  Townsend. 

Finally,  we  wish  to  express  our  thanks  to  the  Honourable  John  P.  Robarts, 
the  Prime  Minister  of  Ontario,  for  his  patience  and  his  understanding  of  the  time 
needed  to  complete  the  task  entrusted  to  us  in  accordance  with  our  terms  of 
reference. 


Xll 


Contents  of  the  Report 

VOLUME  I  APPROACH,  BACKGROUND  AND  CONCLUSIONS 

Chapter     1.     The  Committee's  Philosophy  of  Government  Finance:  Taxation 
Chapter     2.     The  Committee's  Philosophy  of  Government  Finance:  Intergovern- 
mental Fiscal  Relations 
Chapter     3.     The  Committee's  Philosophy  of  Government  Finance:   Provincial 

Fiscal  Policy  and  Public  Borrowing 
Chapter     4.     The  Ontario  Setting:  Patterns  of  Expenditure,  Revenue  and  Debt 
Chapter     5.     The  Incidence  of  Government  Revenue  and  Expenditure 
Chapter     6.     A  Projection  of  the  Expenditure,  Revenue  and  Debt  of  Ontario 

Governments,  1966-75 
Chapter     7.     Recommendations 

Chapter     8.     Fiscal  Effects  of  the  Recommendations:    Prescription   for  Future 
Needs 

VOLUME  11     THE  LOCAL  REVENUE  SYSTEM 

Chapter  9.  Introduction  to  Volume  II 

Chapter  10.  Taxes  on  Property:  Their  History  and  Present  Use  in  Ontario 

Chapter  11.  Taxes  on  Property:  Basic  Issues  and  Policy  Proposals 

Chapter  12.  Taxes  on  Property:  Exemptions 

Chapter  13.  Taxes  on  Property:  Assessment 

Chapter  14.  Taxes  on  Property:  Collections 

Chapter  15.  Special  Capital  Levies  and  Developer  Charges 

Chapter  16.  The  Poll  Tax 

Chapter  17.  Local  Non-Tax  Revenues 

Chapter  18.  Local  Revenue  and  Property  Assessment  Appeals 

Chapter  19.  Some  Possible  New  Sources  of  Municipal  Revenue 

Chapter  20.  School  Finance 

Chapter  21.  Provincial  Grants  to  Municipalities 

Chapter  22.  Municipal  Debt 

Chapter  23.  Reconciling  Structure  with  Finance 

VOLUME  HI     THE  PROVINCIAL  REVENUE  SYSTEM 

Chapter  24.     Introduction  to  Volume  III 

Chapter  25.     Provincial  Revenue  Legislation:  Administration  and  Appeals 

Chapter  26.     The  Personal  Income  Tax 

Chapter  27.     The  Corporations  Tax 

xiii 


Chapter  28.  The  Taxation  of  Wealth:  Death  and  Gift  Taxes 

Chapter  29.  The  Retail  Sales  Tax 

Chapter  30.  Motor  Vehicle  Revenues 

Chapter  31.  Other  Provincial  Taxes 

Chapter  32.  Revenue  from  Mines 

Chapter  33.  Revenue  from  Forest  Resources 

Chapter  34.  Revenue  from  Other  Natural  Resources 

Chapter  35.  Revenue  from  Alcoholic  Beverages 

Chapter  36.  Provincial  Government  Enterprises 

Chapter  37.  Other  Non-Tax  Revenues 

Chapter  38.  Financing  Hospital  and  Medical  Care 

Chapter  39.  Two  Alternative  Sources  of  Provincial  Revenue:  A  Transportation 

Tax  and  Lotteries 

Chapter  40.  Provincial  Debt  Policy  to  1975 


xiv 


VOLUME  I     APPROACH,  BACKGROUND  AND  CONCLUSIONS 


Table  of  Contents 

LETTER  OF  TRANSMITTAL    v 

ORDER-IN-COUNCIL  vii 

THE  ROYAL  COMMISSION  ix 

PREFACE  xi 

CONTENTS  OF  THE  REPORT  xiii 


Chapter  1:  THE  COMMITTEE'S  PHILOSOPHY  OF  GOVERNMENT 
FINANCE:  TAXATION 

INTRODUCTION  1 

CONSTITUTIONAL  DEMOCRACY  AND  TAXATION  2 

Constitutional  Democracy  2 

Democracy  and  the  Common  Good  3 

Constitutionalism  and  Individual  Rights  3 

Constitutional  Democracy  and  Society  5 

Constitutional  Democracy,  Economic  Policy  and  Taxation  6 

EQUITY  IN  TAXATION  8 

The  Principle  of  Equal  Treatment  of  Equals  8 

The  Principle  of  Benefits  Received 9 

The  Principle  of  Ability  to  Pay  11 

OTHER  PRINCIPLES  OF  TAXATION  16 

Adequacy   16 

Flexibility  16 

Elasticity    17 

Balance    17 

Neutrality        18 

Certainty               19 

Simplicity        20 

Convenience  20 

Economy  of  Collection  and  Compliance 20 

CONFLICTS  OF  TAX  PRINCIPLES  21 

TAX  PRINCIPLES  AND  SOCIAL  POLICY  21 

XV 


Contents 

Chapter  2:  THE  COMMITTEE'S  PHILOSOPHY  OF  GOVERNMENT 

FINANCE:  INTERGOVERNMENTAL  FISCAL  RELATIONS 

INTRODUCTION  23 

OUR  PHILOSOPHY  OF  FEDERALISM  AND  ITS  FISCAL 

IMPLICATIONS  24 

The  Nature  of  Federalism  24 

Our  Philosophy  of  Federalism  24 

The  Division  of  Expenditure  Responsibilities  26 

The  Division  of  Revenue  Powers  28 

Joint  Occupancy  of  Tax  Fields  32 

The  Role  of  Grants  34 

The  Taxation  of  Government  Entities  40 

OUR  PHILOSOPHY  OF  PROVINCIAL-MUNICIPAL  RELATIONS 

AND  ITS  FISCAL  IMPLICATIONS  42 

The  Nature  of  the  Provincial-Municipal  Relationship  42 

Our  Philosophy  of  Provincial-Municipal  Relations         43 

The  Division  of  Expenditure  Functions  45 

The  Division  of  Revenue  Sources  46 

The  Role  of  Grants  48 

The  Province  and  Local  Government  Organization  50 

The  Taxation  of  Government  Entities  52 

OUR  PHILOSOPHY  OF  PROVINCIAL-SCHOOL  BOARD 

RELATIONS  AND  ITS  FISCAL  IMPLICATIONS  53 

Principles  of  Provincial-School  Board  Relations  53 

The  Division  of  Expenditure  Responsibilities  54 

The  Division  of  Revenue  Sources  55 

The  Role  of  Grants  56 

The  Province  and  School  Boundaries  57 

Chapter  3:  THE  COMMITTEE'S  PHILOSOPHY  OF  GOVERNMENT 
FINANCE:  PROVINCIAL  FISCAL  POLICY  AND 
PUBLIC  BORROWING 

CHANGING  CONCEPTS  OF  FISCAL  POLICY  59 

INSTRUMENTS  OF  ECONOMIC  POLICY  62 

CONFLICTS  AMONG  ECONOMIC  OBJECTIVES  63 

THE  NEED  FOR  "DISCRETIONARY"  FISCAL  POLICY  65 
INCREASING    IMPORTANCE    OF    PROVINCIAL    AND    MUNICIPAL 

FINANCE  66 

NEED  FOR  INTERGOVERNMENTAL  FISCAL  CO-ORDINATION  67 

xvi 


Volume  1 

FEASIBILITY  OF  PROVINCIAL  COUNTER-CYCLICAL  FISCAL 

POLICY  68 

PHILOSOPHIES  OF  PUBLIC  BORROWING  73 

MUNICIPAL  FINANCE  76 

Chapter  4:  THE  ONTARIO  SETTING: 

PATTERNS  OF  EXPENDITURE,  REVENUE  AND  DEBT 

INTRODUCTION    79 

THE  POPULATION  OF  ONTARIO  80 

Size,  Composition  and  Distribution  80 

Economic  Activities  81 

THE  CHANGING  ROLE  OF  GOVERNMENT  84 

PATTERNS  OF  GOVERNMENT  FINANCE  86 

Expenditure  Patterns  87 

Expenditure  by  Function  95 

Comparison  with  Other  Provinces  98 

Revenue  Patterns  103 

Sources  of  Revenue  107 

Debt  Patterns  115 

CONCLUSION  119 

APPENDIX  TO  CHAPTER  4:  Tables  121 

CHARTS 

4:1      Gross  and  net  money  expenditure,  Province,  municipalities  and  school 

boards,   1939-63 88 

4:2      Indexes  of  expenditure:  Province,  municipalities  and  school  boards, 

1939-63.  90 

4:3      Government  expenditures  by  level  of  ultimate  spending  responsibility, 

1939-63 92 

4:4      Provincial  and  local   net   expenditure  on  goods   and   services   as   a 

percentage  of  provincial  domestic  product,  1939-63.  94 

4:5      Percentage  analysis  of  net  expenditure  for  provincial  functions,  fiscal 

years  ending  March  31,  1945-64.    96 

4:6      Percentage  analysis  of  net  and  gross  local  expenditure  by  function, 

1951-63.  99 

4:7      Combined  provincial  and  local  expenditure  as  a  percentage  of  gross 

domestic  product  in  Ontario  and  in  rest  of  Canada,  1945-62.  101 

4:8      Combined  provincial  and  local  net  general  expenditure  as  a  percentage 

of  personal  income,  by  province,  1952  and  1962.  102 

4:9      Gross  and  net  revenue.  Province,  municipalities  and  school  boards, 

1939-63.  104 

xvii 


Contents 

4:10    Indexes    of   revenue:    Province,    municipalities    and    school    boards, 

1939-63 105 

4:11    Percentage  analysis  of  ordinary  provincial  revenue,  1939-67 109 

4:12    Percentage  analysis  of  gross  municipal  revenues,  1939-63 Ill 

4:13    Percentage  analysis  of  gross  school  board  revenues,  1939-63.  Ill 

4:14    Provincial,  municipal  and  school  board  net  revenues  as  a  percentage 

of  provincial  domestic  product,  1939-63.  113 

4:15    Provincial  net  capital  debt  and  provincial  domestic  product  Ontario, 

1943-66 117 

4:16    Municipal  and  school  board  debt,  Ontario,  selected  years  1939-1964.   118 

TABLES 

4:1      Gross  Money  Expenditures  of  Provincial  Government,  Municipalities 

and  School  Boards,    1939-63 121 

4:2      Net  Money  Expenditures  of  Provincial  Government,   Municipalities 

and  School  Boards,  1939-63 122 

4:3  Net  Money  Expenditures  as  a  Percentage  of  Gross  Money  Expendi- 
tures, Provincial  Government,  Municipalities  and  School  Boards, 
1939-63 123 

4:4      Net  Real  Expenditures  of  Provincial  Government,  Municipalities  and 

School  Boards,  1939-63 124 

4:5      Net  Real  Per-Capita  Expenditures  of  Provincial  Government, 

Municipalities  and  School  Boards,  1939-63.    125 

4:6  Government  Expenditure  by  Level  of  Ultimate  Spending  Responsi- 
bility,   1939-63 126 

4:7      Provincial  and  Local  Net  Real  Expenditure  on  Goods  and  Services; 

National  Accounts  Basis,  1939-63.  127 

4:8  Functional  Classification  of  Net  Expenditures  of  Provincial  Govern- 
ment,   1945-64 128 

4:9  Percentage  Distribution  of  Functional  Classification  of  Net  Expendi- 
tures of  Provincial  Government,  1945-64.    128 

4:10    Functional    Classification    of    Net    General    Expenditures    of    Local 

Governments,   1951-63.   129 

4: 1 1    Percentage  Distribution  of  Functional  Classification  of  Net  General 

Expenditures  of  Local  Governments,  1951-63.  129 

4:12    Functional  Classification  of   Gross   General  Expenditures  of   Local 

Governments,  1952-63.  130 

4:13    Percentage  Distribution  of  Functional  Classification  of  Gross  General 

Expenditures  of  Local  Governments,    1952-63.  130 

4:14  Combined  Provincial  and  Local  Net  General  Expenditure  and  Pro- 
vincial  Domestic   Product,   Ontario  and   Rest  of  Canada,    1945-62.   131 

4: 15    Combined  Provincial  and  Local  Net  General  Expenditure  and  Personal 

Income,  by  Province,  1952  and  1962 131 

xviii 


Volume  1 

4:16    Combined  Provincial  and  Local  Net  General  Expenditure  Per  Capita, 

by  Province,  1952  and  1962 132 

4:17    Principal  Revenues  of  Provincial  Government,   1939-67.    133 

4:18    Percentage  Distribution  of  Principal  Revenues  of  Provincial  Govern- 
ment, 1939-67.  134 

4:19    Provincial  Government  Receipts  from  the  Government  of  Canada  for 

Shared-cost  Programs  and  Grants-in-aid,  1 939-64 135 

4:20    Gross   Money   Revenues   of   Provincial   Government,    Municipalities 

and  School  Boards,  1939-64.  135 

4:21    Net  Money  Revenues  of  Provincial  Government,  Municipalities  and 

School  Boards,    1939-64 136 

4:22    Net  Real  Revenues  of  Provincial  Government,   Municipalities   and 

School  Boards,    1939-64 136 

4:23    Net  Real  Per-Capita  Revenues  of  Provincial  Government,  Munici- 
palities and  School  Boards,  1939-64 137 

4:24    Current  Revenues  of  Municipalities,  1939-63 137 

4:25    Current  Revenues  of  School  Boards,   1939-63 138 

4:26    Provincial,  Municipal  and  School  Board  Net  Real  Revenues  as  a 

Percentage  of  Real  Provincial  Domestic  Product,  1939-63.  138 

4:27    Net  Capital  Debt  of  Provincial  Government  and  Provincial  Domestic 

Product,   1943-66 139 

4:28    Municipal  and  School  Board  Debt  Selected  Years,  1939-1964 140 


Chapter  5:  THE  INCIDENCE  OF  GOVERNMENT 
REVENUE  AND  EXPENDITURE 

INTRODUCTION  141 

THE  BASIS  OF  ESTIMATING  INCIDENCE  144 

The  Method  of  Estimating  the  Incidence  of  Government  Expenditures     .  149 

BURDENS  AND  BENEFITS,  BY  MONEY-INCOME  CLASSES  151 

EFFECTIVE  RATES  OF  INCIDENCE  154 

Adjusted  Broad  Income  154 

Effective  Tax  Rates    154 

Effective  Benefit  Rates  158 

The  Concept  of  Net  Fiscal  Incidence  161 

The  Pattern  of  Net  Fiscal  Incidence  Among  Ontario  Residents  163 

GENERAL  CONCLUSIONS  165 

APPENDIX  TO  CHAPTER  5  167 

xix 


Contents 

Assumptions  Regarding  the  Shifting  and  Incidence  of  Major  Revenue 

Sources  1 67 

Assumptions  Regarding  the  Allocation  of  Benefits  from  Major  Expendi- 
ture Programs  1 69 

CHARTS 

5:1      Effective  tax  (burden)  rates  of  provincial  and  municipal  governments 

in  Ontario,    1961 156 

5:2      Effective    expenditure    (benefit)    rates  of   provincial    and    municipal 

governments  in  Ontario,  1961 159 

5:3      Net  fiscal  incidence  rates,   1961.   164 

TABLES 

5:1      Governmental  Revenues  by  Source,  1961  145 

5:2      Distribution  of  Tax  Burdens,  by  Family  Money-Income  Classes,  1961  146 

5:3      Allocation  of  Governmental  Expenditures,  1961  151 

5:4      Distribution  of  Government  Expenditures  by  Family  Money-Income 

Classes,  1961   152 

5:5      Derivation  and  Distribution  of  Adjusted  Broad  Income,  1961  155 

5:6      Effective  Revenue  Rates  for  Selected  Governments  of  Canada,  1961  157 

5:7      Effective  Expenditure  Rates  for  Selected  Governments  in  Canada,  1961  160 
5:8      "Net  Fiscal  Incidence"  of  the  Revenue  and  Expenditure  Programs  of 

Selected  Governments  in  Canada,  1961  163 

Chapter  6:    A  PROJECTION   OF  THE   EXPENDITURE,   REVENUE   AND 
DEBT  OF  ONTARIO  GOVERNMENTS,  1966-75 

INTRODUCTION  171 

BASIC  ASSUMPTIONS  OF  THE  PROJECTION  172 

PROJECTION  OF  POPULATION,  LABOUR  FORCE,  EMPLOYMENT, 

AND  PROVINCIAL  DOMESTIC  PRODUCT  173 

Population    174 

Labour  Force  174 

Provincial  Domestic  Product  175 

PROJECTION  OF  MUNICIPAL  AND  SCHOOL  BOARD  REVENUE, 

EXPENDITURE  AND  DEBT  177 

Municipal  Revenues  177 

School  Board  Expenditure  179 

Municipal   Expenditure 180 

Grants  to  Local  Governments  from  the  Province  181 

Budgetary  and  Debt  Position    183 

PROJECTIONS  OF  PROVINCIAL  REVENUE    185 

Share  of  Federal  Estate  Tax                  185 

XX 


Volume  1 

Gasoline  Tax  185 

Motor  Vehicle  Licences  and  Permits  186 

Personal  Income  Tax  186 

Other  Current  Revenue  187 

PROJECTIONS  OF  PROVINCIAL  EXPENDITURE  187 

Education  1 87 

Highways  and  Roads 197 

Health  198 

Construction  of  Public  Buildings  200 

Other  Capital  Expenditure  200 

.  Other   Current  Expenditure     200 

Grants  to  Municipalities  and  School  Boards  200 

PROJECTION  OF  PROVINCIAL  BUDGETARY  AND  DEBT  POSITION  201 

Combined  Provincial  and  Local  Budgetary  and  Debt  Position  203 

CONCLUSION    204 

APPENDIX  TO  CHAPTER   6    206 

Detailed  Projections  206 

Note  Concerning  the  Method  Used  in  Projecting  Personal  Income 

Tax  Revenue  216 

Note  on  Projection  as  of  Spring  1967  217 

TABLES 

6:1      Projected  Growth  of  Population,  Labour  Force,  Employment,   and 

Provincial  Domestic  Product  for  Ontario  174 

6:2      Municipal  Revenues  177 

6:3      Expenditure  by  Elementary  and  Secondary  School  Boards  179 

6:4      Municipal  Current  and  Capital  Expenditure  180 

6:5      Local  Government  Grants  Received  from  the  Province  182 

6:6  Budgetary  and  Debt  Position  of  Local  Governments  183 
6:7      Revenues  of  the  Government  of  Ontario — Fiscal  Years  ending 

March  31  186 

6:8      Distribution  of  Post-Secondary  Students  in  Ontario  190 

6:9      Costs  to  the  Government  of  Ontario  of  Post-Secondary  Education  194 

6:10  Government  of  Ontario  Expenditures  on  Highways  and  Roads  197 
6:11    Government  of  Ontario  Expenditures  on  Hospitals  and  Health — Major 

Items                            199 

6:12  Budgetary  and  Debt  Position  of  the  Government  of  Ontario  201 
6:13    Combined  Provincial   and  Local  Government  Budgetary   and  Debt 

Position  203 
6:14    Projected  Growth  of  Population,  Labour  Force,  Employment,  and 

Provincial  Domestic  Product  for  Ontario,  1963-74  206 

6:15    Municipal  Current  Revenues,  1963-74          207 

xxi 


Contents 

6:16    Expenditure  by  Elementary  and  Secondary  School  Boards,  1963-74        207 

6:17    Municipal  Current  and  Capital  Expenditure,  1963-74  208 

6:18    Local  Government  Grants  Received  from  the  Province,  1963-74  208 

6:19    Budgetary  and  Debt  Position  of  Local  Governments,  1963-74  209 

6:20    Net  Ordinary  Revenues  of  the  Government  of  Ontario,  1964-75  210 

6:21    Distribution  of  Post-Secondary  Students  in  Ontario,  1965-74  210 

6:22    Costs  to  the  Government  of  Ontario  of  Post-Secondary  Education, 

1964-75    211 

6:23    Government  of  Ontario  Expenditures   on  Highways  and  Roads, 

1964-75 212 

6:24    Government  of  Ontario  Expenditures  on  Hospitals  and  Health — Major 

Items,  1964-75  212 

6:25    Other  Government  of  Ontario  Expenditures,  1964-75  213 

6:26  Budgetary  and  Debt  Position  of  the  Government  of  Ontario,  1964-75  214 
6:27    Combined  Provincial  and  Local  Government  Budgetary   and  Debt 

Position,    1963-74   215 

Chapter  7:  RECOMMENDATIONS 

INTRODUCTION  219 

FISCAL  EFFECTS  OF  THE  RECOMMENDATIONS:  PRESCRIPTION 

FOR  FUTURE  NEEDS  219 

INTRODUCTION  TO  VOLUME  II    220 

TAXES  ON  PROPERTY:  BASIC  ISSUES  AND  POLICY  PROPOSALS        220 

TAXES  ON  PROPERTY:  EXEMPTIONS   223 

TAXES  ON  PROPERTY:   ASSESSMENT   227 

TAXES  ON  PROPERTY:   COLLECTIONS   228 

SPECIAL  CAPITAL  LEVIES  AND  DEVELOPER  CHARGES  229 

THE  POLL  TAX  230 

LOCAL  NON-TAX  REVENUES  230 

LOCAL  REVENUE  AND  PROPERTY  ASSESSMENT  APPEALS  231 

SCHOOL  FINANCE   232 

PROVINCIAL  GRANTS  TO  MUNICIPALITIES  233 

MUNICIPAL  DEBT      236 

RECONCILING  STRUCTURE  WITH  FINANCE  238 

INTRODUCTION  TO  VOLUME  III  238 

PROVINCIAL   REVENUE    LEGISLATION:    ADMINISTRATION    AND 

APPEALS  238 

xxii 


Volume  1 

THE  PERSONAL  INCOME  TAX  240 

THE  CORPORATIONS  TAX    242 

THE  TAXATION  OF  WEALTH:  DEATH  AND  GIFT  TAXES  243 

THE  RETAIL  SALES  TAX  251 

MOTOR  VEHICLE  REVENUES  252 

OTHER  PROVINCIAL  TAXES  253 

REVENUE  FROM  MINES  254 

REVENUE  FROM  FOREST  RESOURCES  257 

REVENUE  FROM  OTHER  NATURAL  RESOURCES  257 

REVENUE  FROM  ALCOHOLIC  BEVERAGES  257 

PROVINCIAL  GOVERNMENT  ENTERPRISES  259 

OTHER  NON-TAX  REVENUES  259 

FINANCING  HOSPITAL  AND  MEDICAL  CARE  259 

PROVINCIAL  DEBT  POLICY  TO  1975    260 

Chapter  8:  FISCAL  EFFECTS  OF  THE  RECOMMENDATIONS: 
PRESCRIPTION  FOR  FUTURE  NEEDS 

INTRODUCTION  261 

THE  FISCAL  SCENE  IN  1966-67  262 

THE  FISCAL  SCENE:   1968-75   272 

THE  FISCAL  SCENE:  CONCLUDING  COMMENTS  280 

TABLES 

8:1      The  Fiscal  Effect  on  Local  Governments,  had  Recommendations  made 

in  Volumes  II  and  III  been  effective  in  1966  263 

8:2  The  Fiscal  Effect  on  the  Provincial  Government,  had  Recommenda- 
tions made  in  Volumes  II  and  III  been  effective  in  1966-67  265 

8:3  The  Fiscal  Effect  on  the  Provincial  Government  for  1966-67,  Assuming 
changes  recommended  in  Volumes  II  and  III,  increased  Provincial 
School  Grants,  and  Tax  Rate  Changes  necessary  to  maintain  a  Reason- 
able Ratio  of  Debt  to  Provincial  Domestic  Product  267 

8:4  The  Fiscal  Effect  on  Local  Government  for  1966,  Assuming  changes 
recommended  in  Volumes  II  and  III,  and  increased  Provincial  School 
Grants    271 

8:5  Projected  Provincial  Deficit  after  Recommendations,  including  Pro- 
vision for  Higher  School  Grants,  but  before  Tax  Rate  changes,  in 
Selected  Fiscal  Years  1968-75  274 

8:6      Tax   Rate   Changes   Required   to  Cope   with   Deficits    Projected    in 

Table  8:5  275 

xxiii 


Contents 

8:7      Rates  of  Tax  that  would  be  in  effect  after  Rate  changes  compared  to 

actual  rates  as  of  January  1,  1967  276 

8:8      Projected  Provincial  Deficit  before  and  after  Tax  Rate  changes,  and 

resulting  net  capital   debt  position    279 

8:9  Local  Expenditure,  Revenue  and  Debt  Position,  Assuming  Implemen- 
tation of  the  Recommendations  279 

8:10  Effective  Levy  on  Local  Property  Taxpayers,  Assuming  Implementa- 
tion of  the  Recommendations  as  a  Percentage  of  Projected  Tax  280 

APPENDIX  A:  Organizations  from  Which  Submissions  Were  Received  284 

APPENDIX  B:  Individuals  from  Whom  Submissions  Were  Received 287 

APPENDIX  C:  Staff  and  Consultants  289 

APPENDIX  D:  Studies  to  be  Published  by  the  Committee  292 

INDEX  293 


XXIV 


Chapter 
1 


The  Committee's  Philosophy 
of  Government  Finance: 
Taxation 


INTRODUCTION 

1.  This  Report  contains  the  results  of  an  inquiry  in  which  we,  as  commis- 
sioners, have  attempted  to  fulfil  our  mandate  to  examine  the  taxation  and  revenue 
system  of  the  Province  of  Ontario,  its  municipalities  and  school  boards.  Specifically, 
our  instructions  were  to  carry  out  this  investigation  with  particular  regard  to 
whether  "the  tax  and  revenue  system  is  as  simple,  clear,  equitable,  efficient, 
adequate  and  as  conducive  to  the  sound  growth  of  the  Province  as  can  be  devised". 
That  our  undertaking  was  not  an  easy  one  is  already  evident  from  the  length  of 
time — more  than  four  years — which  the  preparation  of  this  P.eport  has  consumed. 
The  many  chapters  that  follow,  occasionally  technical  and  frequently  long  but 
always,  we  trust,  pertinent,  now  confront  the  reader  with  his  own  demanding  task: 
that  of  appraising  the  significance  of  our  work. 

2.  We  hope  that  this  task  will  be  eased  somewhat  if  we  begin  the  Report 
with  a  discussion  of  the  basic  philosophy  on  which  we  have  reached  agreement 
concerning  the  role  of  government  in  society,  including  the  financing  of  its 
activities.    We  recognize  that  the  personal  philosophies  that  commissioners  may 

1 


Philosophy  of  Taxation 

hold  will  necessarily  influence  the  substance  of  their  recommendations  designed 
to  improve  the  performance  of  a  tax  system.  Granted  that  the  logical  analysis 
of  facts  is  an  indispensable  prerequisite  to  sound  conclusions,  it  remains  true 
that  different  underlying  philosophies  may  lead,  from  the  same  set  of  facts,  to 
rather  different  conclusions  about  what  constitutes  an  optimum  tax  structure.  To 
put  the  matter  somewhat  differently,  the  soundness  of  a  tax  system  must  be  judged 
not  only  in  the  light  of  its  technical  performance  but  also  in  relation  to  the 
particular  priorities  that  one  attaches  to  its  various  objectives,  not  all  of  which  may 
be  mutually  compatible.  For  these  reasons,  we  have  tried  throughout  this  Report 
to  relate  each  of  our  recommendations  to  the  underlying  philosophical  principles 
we  arrived  at  in  the  course  of  our  public  hearings,  studies  and  discussions.  In  the 
interest  of  convenience  and  manageable  organization,  the  present  chapter  deals 
primarily  with  our  basic  position  on  taxation,  in  particular  with  respect  to  revenue 
which  is  raised  and  spent  by  the  same  level  of  government.  The  second  chapter 
will  develop  our  underlying  premises  with  regard  to  intergovernmental  relations, 
critically  important  because  federal,  provincial  and  local  influences  are  all  at 
work  in  Ontario;  and  the  third  the  philosophical  consensus  we  have  reached  on 
fiscal  policy  and  public  debt. 

CONSTITUTIONAL  DEMOCRACY  AND  TAXATION 
CONSTITUTIONAL  DEMOCRACY 

3.  The  reconciliation  of  governmental  power  with  individual  rights  is  a  prob- 
lem as  old  as  human  society  itself.  Centuries  of  evolution,  and  sometimes 
revolution,  have  yielded  in  much  of  the  western  world  a  mode  of  governmental 
organization  that  is  indeUbly  stamped  by  the  quest  for  such  a  reconciliation.  This 
mode  of  government  is  commonly  called  constitutional  democracy.  Constitutional 
democracy  can  assume  different  forms  in  different  countries,  but  its  most  classic 
types  are  the  parliamentary  form  as  practised  in  the  United  Kingdom  and  Canada, 
and  the  presidential-congressional  of  which  the  United  States  is  the  progenitor 
and  leading  example. 

4.  Whatever  particular  forms  developed  to  suit  their  peculiar  circumstances, 
all  constitutional  democracies  share  two  basic  elements.  The  first,  the  "demo- 
cratic" element,  attempts  to  ensure  government  that  is  at  once  responsive  and 
responsible.  This  it  does  by  providing  for  periodic  competitive  elections  on  the 
basis  of  something  approaching  universal  adult  suffrage  and  for  constant  ready 
access  to  governing  representatives  on  the  part  of  the  governed,  whether  as  indi- 
viduals or  as  groups.  The  second,  the  "constitutional"  element,  consists  of  built-in 
practices  designed  to  restrain  abuses  of  government  power.  The  rule  of  law,  the 
independence  of  the  judiciary,  and  legislative  oversight  of  the  executive  are  the 
best  known  of  these  restraining  devices.  At  this  point,  we  think  it  appropriate 
to  develop  two  philosophical  positions  to  which  we  wholeheartedly  subscribe. 
The  first  concerns  democracy,  the  second  constitutionalism. 


Chapter   1:    Paragraphs  3-7 

DEMOCRACY  AND  THE  COMMON  GOOD 

5.  It  is  a  long-held  axiom  that  government  exists  for  the  promotion  of  some- 
thing that  is  variously  called  the  "common  good",  the  "public  interest",  the  "general 
welfare";  namely,  the  well-being,  material  and  otherwise,  of  its  citizens.  Demo- 
cratic governments  seek  out  the  "common  good"  through  a  variety  of  processes, 
the  best-known  of  which  are  majority  vote,  the  reconciliation  of  competing  group 
claims,  and  the  quest  for  consensus  through  deliberation.  However,  it  is  a  dan- 
gerous and  not  uncommon  fallacy  to  equate  the  "common  good"  with  the  process 
through  which  it  is  reached.  We  believe  that  the  "common  good"  evokes  some- 
thing more  than  majority  rule,  the  outcome  of  group  conflict  or  the  politics  of 
consensus.  This  is  because  one  set  of  policies  is  not  just  as  good  as  any  other, 
even  though  it  may  be  the  temporary  outcome  of  the  democratic  process.  Ration- 
ality, in  the  raising  and  spending  of  public  funds  as  in  other  areas,  requires 
the  making  of  difficult  choices  in  the  light  of  the  expected  consequences  of  alterna- 
tive courses  of  action.  It  is  always  distinctly  possible  that  a  given  choice  made 
by  consensus  or  majority  rule  will  be  based  on  misapprehension  or  unawareness  of 
the  underlying  facts  and  hence  will  be  irrational.  Alternatively,  it  may  be  that 
through  inertia,  a  particular  minority  is  allowed  to  dictate  a  policy  or  another 
minority  is  placed  at  such  a  disadvantage  that  the  basic  rights  of  its  members  have 
been  prejudiced. 

6.  The  achievement  of  the  common  good,  then,  depends  on  more  than  the 
existence  of  democratic  processes  through  which  policies  are  devised.  It  will 
require  from  each  individual  a  genuine  concern  for  the  needs  of  others  and  a 
consequent  refusal  to  use  others  simply  as  a  means  of  promoting  his  private  or 
pubUc  objectives,  however  laudable  these  may  be  made  to  appear.  It  will  depend, 
too,  on  the  continuous  use  of  the  individual's  powers  in  the  maintenance  and 
enlargement  of  freedom  in  human  relationships.  Finally,  the  common  good  will 
always  require  the  orientation  of  public  policy  to  the  general  well-being  of  society 
rather  than  to  particular  interests.  When,  for  example,  it  is  proposed  that  selective 
tax  concessions  be  granted  to  particular  sectors  of  the  economy,  the  proponents 
will  clearly  bear  the  onus  for  proving  that  such  a  policy  will  best  further  the 
public  interest.  Because  the  furthering  of  the  common  good  does  represent  the 
fundamental  task  of  democratic  government,  government's  use  of  the  tax  system 
must  always  be  judged  in  relation  to  that  end. 

CONSTITUTIONALISM  AND  INDIVIDUAL  RIGHTS 

7.  If  the  basic  purpose  of  democratic  government  is  the  pursuit  of  the  com- 
mon good,  constitutionalism  exists  to  safeguard  individual  rights  in  the  face  of 
any  aberrations  or  deviations  that  will  necessarily  arise  from  time  to  time  as 
falUble  governments  press  on  in  their  quest  for  the  public  welfare.  While  there 
is  considerable  disagreement  over  the  source  of  individual  rights — whether  from 
divine  intent,  human  reason  or  sociological  conditions — there  exists  remarkable 
consensus  as  to  their  content.  We  wish  to  comment  briefly  on  three  widely 
recognized  individual  rights,  not  because  we  necessarily  prize  them  more  highly 


Philosophy  of  Taxation 

than  others,  but  because  they  are  particularly  relevant  to  the  field  of  taxation. 
The  first  is  the  right  to  equal  treatment  before  the  law,  the  second  is  the  right  of 
the  individual  to  earn,  own  and  dispose  of  private  property,  and  the  third  is  the 
right  of  the  individual  to  a  minimum  level  of  economic  and  social  well-being — 
all  essential  to  achieve  both  the  free  exercise  of  constitutional  rights  and  the 
equitable  distribution  of  the  fruits  of  economic  growth. 

8.  Each  of  these  rights  imposes  corresponding  duties  and  obligations  on  the 
individual.  With  the  right  to  equal  treatment  before  the  law  goes  the  obligation 
to  uphold  and  respect  the  law.  The  right  to  property  carries  with  it  the  duty  to 
earn,  own  and  dispose  of  property  with  due  concern  for  the  welfare  of  society 
and  the  rights  of  others.  And  with  the  right  of  the  individual  to  a  minimum 
standard  of  economic  and  social  well-being  goes  the  obligation  to  make  every 
reasonable  effort  to  provide  adequately  for  his  needs. 

9.  The  right  to  equal  treatment  before  the  law  is  one  of  the  principal  reasons 
for  constitutionalism.  Restraints  against  arbitrary  and  capricious  legislation,  the 
independence  of  the  judiciary,  legislative  checks  on  executive  power,  all  are 
designed  to  secure  for  the  individual  this  basic  right.  Tax  laws,  no  less  than  other 
kinds  of  legislation,  must  be  tailored  and  applied  with  strict  adherence  to  the 
letter  and  spirit  of  this  right.  However,  both  because  taxation  so  intimately  affects 
every  individual  and  because  it  is  heavily  dependent  on  administrative  processes, 
the  achievement  of  strict  equity  in  this  field  poses  an  unusually  severe  challenge. 
Our  concern  for  the  equal  treatment  of  equals  in  matters  of  taxation  is  such  that 
it  pervades  this  entire  Report.  We  consider  equity  in  tax  law  and  tax  administration 
a  prime  test  both  of  a  sound  revenue  system  and,  more  important,  of  truly 
functional  constitutionalism. 

10.  If  the  capacity  of  constitutionalism  to  guarantee  equaUty  before  the  law 
is  exceedingly  important  in  matters  of  taxation,  so  too  is  its  ability  to  sustain  and 
protect  the  individual's  right  to  private  property,  a  bulwark  of  human  freedom 
and  one  of  the  basic  ethical  postulates  of  the  competitive  market  economy.  Taxa- 
tion, which  by  definition  is  a  compulsory  contribution  to  the  support  of  govern- 
ment, directly  affects  property  rights.  Property,  of  course,  is  generally  recognized 
as  an  individual  right  that  is  strongly  conditioned  by  the  existence  of  a  social 
order.  Hence  taxation  is  not  a  negation  of  the  right  to  property  and  indeed, 
because  it  finances  the  maintenance  of  the  social  order,  complements  rather  than 
contradicts  this  right.  However,  because  it  is  a  self-evident  proposition  that 
arbitrary  and  inequitable  taxation  will  impinge  on  the  individual's  right  to  property, 
equity  in  taxation  is  a  desideratum  based  no  less  on  his  right  to  property  than  on 
his  standing  before  the  law. 

1 1 .  The  right  of  the  individual  to  a  minimum  level  of  economic  and  social 
well-being  is  derived  not  only  from  humane  considerations,  but  from  his  right  to 
property  and  ultimately  to  liberty.  Freedom  without  bread  is  an  illusion.  However, 
this  right  has  imposed  on  constitutional  government  new  responsibilities  that 
differ  markedly  from  those  necessary  to  preserve  private  property  and  maintain 


Chapter  1:  Paragraphs  8-13 

equal  treatment  before  the  law.  The  latter  age-old  rights  emphasize  the  limits 
within  which  government  must  operate.  But  the  right  to  a  minimum  level  of 
economic  and  social  well-being,  to  be  effective,  requires  direct  action  by  govern- 
ment. The  proper  scope  of  such  action  by  no  means  commands  general  under- 
standing or  agreement,  although  it  is  clear  that  measures  which  are  unduly  adverse 
to  economic  growth  must  be  avoided.  Government,  therefore,  should  direct  its 
economic  policies  primarily  to  promoting  an  environment  in  which  the  full  poten- 
tial of  the  economy  will  be  realized.  This  involves  ensuring  opportunities  for  the 
full  and  productive  employment  of  a  continuously  expanding  labour  force.  As  an 
important  adjunct,  government  must  also  develop  social  welfare  programs  for 
those  who  are  prevented  by  circumstances  beyond  their  own  control  from  pro- 
viding adequately  for  their  own  needs.  As  we  show  subsequently  in  our  analysis 
of  the  burden  of  public  expenditures  and  revenues,  the  present  pattern  of  govern- 
ment finance  in  Ontario  has  produced,  through  a  combination  of  social  expen- 
ditures and  progressive  taxation,  a  significant  redistribution  of  income.  Such  a 
process  of  redistribution  is,  of  course,  not  an  end  in  itself  but  is  deemed  to 
contribute  to  both  equity  and  economic  efficiency.  It  reflects  a  widespread  beUef 
that  a  less  uneven  distribution  of  income  than  that  produced  initially  by  the 
market  mechanism  is  a  legitimate  aspect  of  economic  policy. 

CONSTITUTIONAL  DEMOCRACY  AND  SOCIETY 

12.  Constitutional  democracy  enables  individuals  to  seek  out  collectively  their 
common  good  through  a  government  that  is  under  regular  and  recognized  restraints. 
While  we  have  no  doubts  about  the  superiority  of  constitutional  democracy  as  a 
mode  of  government,  we  also  believe  that  governments,  however  constitutional  and 
democratic,  should  not  have  an  unlimited  sphere  of  activity.  Surely  the  permissible 
scope  of  government  does  not  extend  to  all  aspects  of  social  organization.  The 
market  economy,  with  its  private  incentives  and  with  the  opportunities  it  extends  to 
all  to  exercise  responsibiUty  in  the  use  of  property,  is  essential  for  the  most  efficient 
production  and  distribution  of  goods  and  services.  Business  firms,  labour  unions, 
private  associations,  local  governments,  all  are  vital  components  of  efficiency  and 
freedom. 

13.  A  governmental  sphere  that  extended  to  every  aspect  of  human  life  would 
be  no  less  a  monolith  by  virtue  of  its  constitutionalism  and  democracy.  As  John 
Stuart  Mill  noted  over  a  century  ago  in  his  celebrated  essay  "On  Liberty": 

The  .  .  .  most  cogent  reason  for  restricting  the  interference  of  government  is  the 
great  evil  of  adding  unnecessarily  to  its  power.  Every  function  superadded  to 
those  already  exercised  by  the  government  causes  its  influence  over  hopes  and 
fears  to  be  more  widely  diffused,  and  converts,  more  and  more,  the  active  and 
ambitious  part  of  the  public  into  hangers-on  of  the  government,  or  of  some  party 
which  aims  at  becoming  the  government.  If  the  roads,  the  railways,  the  banks, 
the  insurance  offices,  the  great  joint-stock  companies,  the  universities,  and  the 
public  charities,  were  all  of  them  branches  of  the  government;  if,  in  addition, 
the  municipal  corporations  and  local  boards  .  .  .  became  departments  of  the 
central  administration;  if  the  employes  of  all  these  different  enterprises  were 
appointed  and  paid  by  the  government  and  looked  to  the  government  for  every 


Philosophy  of  Taxation 

rise  in  life;  not  all  the  freedom  of  the  press  and  popular  constitution  of  the 
legislature  would  make  this  or  any  other  country  free  otherwise  than  in  name.^ 

14.  The  key  phrase  in  the  above  quotation  is  that  which  refers  to  the  evil  of 
"adding  unnecessarily"  to  the  power  of  government.  In  the  economic  development 
of  their  country,  Canadians  have  fortunately  at  all  times  adopted  a  pragmatic 
approach  to  the  role  of  government  in  economic  affairs,  a  role  that  since  earliest 
times  has  been  substantial.  Whether  as  the  guarantor  of  the  institutional  framework 
within  which  private  enterprise  must  operate,  or  in  initiating  public  policies  designed 
to  influence  strongly  the  prevailing  economic  climate,  or  in  directly  producing 
goods  and  services  for  its  citizens,  or  in  exercising  its  responsibility  for  regulating 
the  use  of  private  property  in  the  public  interest,  government  must  continue  to 
exercise  a  pervasive  influence  if  the  country's  economic  objectives  are  to  be  attained. 
But  however  beneficent  the  role  of  government,  it  is  surely  dangerous  to  suppose 
that  there  exist  no  limits  on  its  encroachments.  Excessive  concentrations  of  power 
are  no  less  to  be  feared  when  they  involve  big  government  than  they  are  when  they 
involve  big  business,  big  labour  or  big  agriculture. 

15.  At  this  point  we  beheve  it  important  to  single  out  a  substantial  advantage 
that  accrues  to  this  country  from  its  multi-level  governmental  structure — federal, 
provincial  and  local.  We  regard  the  existence  of  a  plurality  of  governmental  levels, 
each  with  its  own  sphere  of  responsibility,  as  conferring  singularly  effective  safe- 
guards against  the  abuse  of  power.  A  rational  distribution  of  revenue  sources  and 
expenditure  functions  among  several  levels  of  government,  each  strong  and  viable, 
is  one  of  the  surest  antidotes  to  monolithic  public  power.  The  basic  principles  that 
should  underlie  such  a  distribution  form  the  substance  of  the  next  chapter. 


CONSTITUTIONAL  DEMOCRACY,  ECONOMIC  POLICY  AND  TAXATION 

16.  To  say  that  there  are  limits  to  the  appropriate  scope  of  government  is  not 
to  deny  that  government  must  play  a  critically  important  role  in  society,  more  par- 
ticularly in  economic  life.  Such  a  denial  would  surely  fly  in  the  face  of  reality. 
Indeed,  there  are  at  least  five  major  economic  objectives  that  are  so  generally 
recognized  as  falling  within  the  purview  of  government  that  an  enumeration  is 
almost  superfluous.  These  objectives  can  be  summarized  as: 

( 1 )  a  high  and  stable  level  of  employment,  which  is  not  only  essential  to  the 
most  efficient  use  of  available  productive  resources  but  is  a  basic  founda- 
tion of  human  welfare  and  dignity; 

(2)  reasonable  stability  of  the  general  price  level,  a  fundamental  condition 
for  economic  efficiency  and  highly  important  to  the  achievement  of 
equity  and  to  the  protection  of  savings; 

(3)  economic  growth,  defined  as  a  rising  per-capita  annual  production  of 
goods  and  services,  a  process  vital  to  continuing  improvement  in  the 


^John  Stuart  Mill,  "On  Liberty",  Utilitarianism,  Liberty  and  Representative  Government, 
London:  Everyman's  Library,  1910,  p.  165. 


Chapter  1:  Paragraphs  14-19 

standard  of  living — improvement  that  makes  possible  wider  choices  over 
the  entire  range  of  public  and  private  goods  and  services; 

(4)  an  equitable  distribution  of  income,  necessary  not  only  to  provide  incen- 
tives and  to  ensure  the  basic  right  of  all  individuals  to  a  minimum  level 
of  economic  and  social  well-being,  but  also  to  prevent  undue  concen- 
trations of  private  economic  power  and  to  lessen  the  severity  of  cyclical 
swings  in  the  level  of  economic  activity; 

(5)  the  promotion  and  regulation  of  competition,  with  a  view  to  furthering 
the  healthiest  possible  market  economy. 

17.  These  objectives  are  the  legitimate  concern  of  government  because  it  has 
become  clear  that  the  market  mechanism,  unaided,  cannot  be  relied  upon  to  achieve 
them  in  satisfactory  measure.  In  particular,  the  private  market  economy  by  itself 
is  clearly  incapable  of  assuring  stability  in  employment  and  price  levels  and  of 
achieving  an  optimal  and  balanced  rate  of  growth.  Nor  does  the  market  economy 
of  itself  guarantee  an  equitable  distribution  of  goods  and  services.  Some  services, 
such  as  education,  highways,  police  and  fire  protection,  confer  such  general  social 
benefits  that  they  must  be  provided  collectively;  others,  such  as  welfare  programs, 
are  necessitated  both  by  humane  considerations  and  by  the  need  to  maintain  a  high 
and  stable  level  of  aggregate  consumption.  Finally,  the  susceptibility  of  the  private 
economy  to  monopolistic  influences,  whether  in  industry,  labour,  agriculture  or 
elsewhere,  means  that  its  effective  functioning  must  be  the  constant  concern  of 
government. 

18.  In  the  light  of  what  are  necessary  objectives  of  economic  policy  in  all 
constitutional  democracies,  the  tax  system  takes  on  a  particular  degree  of  impor- 
tance. Taxation  is,  of  course,  necessary  as  the  means  of  financing  all  but  those 
very  few  government  services — electricity,  for  example — that  can  be  priced  like 
any  private  good  and  charged  directly  to  the  user.  But  in  addition  taxation, 
because  it  influences  the  distribution  of  income,  the  level  of  demand  for  goods  and 
services,  and  the  allocation  of  resources  between  public  and  private  uses,  can  be 
an  invaluable  component  of  policies  designed  to  secure  full  employment,  price 
stability  and  balanced  growth.  The  potential  economic  effects  of  the  tax  system 
therefore  make  its  functioning  a  matter  of  special  concern. 

19.  Taxation,  to  be  sure,  is  but  one  tool  that  governments  utilize  in  their  quest 
to  meet  the  economic  objectives  of  society.  Public  expenditures,  debt  management, 
monetary  policy  and  regulatory  legislation  are  other  tools  that,  along  with 
taxation,  are  directed  to  the  attainment  of  optimal  economic  policies.  The  problem 
of  integrating  these  various  tools  forms  the  subject  of  a  later  chapter.  In  the 
context  of  the  present  discussion,  however,  we  wish  to  suggest  that  the  objectives  of 
taxation  may  be  described  either  in  the  immediate  sense — that  of  raising  the 
revenues  necessary  for  discharging  the  responsibilities  assumed  by  or  allocated  to 
a  particular  level  of  government — or  in  the  ultimate  sense — that  of  furthering  the 
basic  economic  objectives  of  the  community.  It  is  in  the  light  of  these  ultimate 
objectives  that  the  performance  of  the  tax  system  must  in  the  end  be  assessed. 


Philosophy  of  Taxation 

20.  Whether  in  terms  of  its  immediate  or  its  ultimate  objectives,  a  sound  tax 
system  should  possess  certain  important  characteristics.  The  process  of  identifying 
and  developing  these  characteristics  is  the  task  of  the  remaining  sections  of  this 
chapter.  But  there  is  one  characteristic  in  particular  that  in  our  view  rises  above 
all  the  rest,  both  because  a  majority  of  the  remaining  characteristics  flow  from  it 
and  because  it  goes  to  the  core  of  constitutional  democracy.  This  characteristic 
is  equity. 

EQUITY  IN  TAXATION 

THE  PRINCIPLE  OF  EQUAL  TREATMENT  OF  EQUALS 

21.  The  basic  rule  of  equity  in  taxation  is  the  principle  of  equal  treatment  of 
equals.  This  principle  is  basic  because  it  is  derived  from  the  equality  of  individuals 
before  the  law,  which  we  have  already  referred  to  as  a  fundamental  right  of  man. 
Furthermore  it  is  applicable  to  all  types  of  taxation  since  all  taxes  are  ultimately 
paid  by  the  individual.  To  be  sure,  a  substantial  proportion  of  taxes  are  paid  in 
the  first  instance  not  by  individuals  but  by  incorporated  enterprises  which  have  a 
legal  identity  apart  from  their  owners.  In  the  long  run,  however,  corporations 
are  simply  intermediaries  for  collecting  revenues  from  individuals,  whether  as 
consumers,  owners  or  employees.  In  exceptional  circumstances,  a  tax  may  be 
shifted  in  its  entirety  to  the  consumers  of  a  firm's  product,  or  to  the  owners  of  the 
enterprise,  or  to  the  suppUers  of  labour  and  other  resources  employed  by  the 
business.  More  commonly,  the  tax  burden  will  be  shared  among  these  interests, 
the  proportion  of  sharing  being  related  to  market  conditions  and  to  the  period  of 
time  within  which  shifting  takes  place.  Whatever  the  case,  the  upshot  is  that  since 
all  taxes  are  ultimately  paid  by  individuals,  the  principle  of  equal  treatment  of 
equals  is  always  a  relevant  consideration  and  its  application  should  look  beyond 
the  entity  on  which  any  tax  is  first  imposed  to  the  individuals  on  whom  the  burden 
of  tax  finally  rests. 

22.  In  an  imperfect  world,  it  is  quite  obvious  that  the  principle  of  equal 
treatment  of  equals  can  never  be  realized  fully.  Even  if  one  could  assume  general 
agreement  as  to  what  constituted  the  total  fulfilment  of  this  principle,  other  objec- 
tives might  conflict  with  equity,  objectives  whose  achievement  was  deemed  by 
society  to  warrant  marginal  sacrifices  in  equity.  Then  too,  our  limited  knowledge 
of  tax  shifting  means  that  we  cannot  pretend  to  know  precisely  the  incidence  or 
ultimate  impact  of  many  taxes.  To  recognize  these  impediments  is  in  no  way  to 
deprecate  equity  but  is  simply  to  face  up  to  the  practical  difficulties  that  beset  its 
achievement.  Such  recognition  also  points  to  at  least  one  significant  conclusion, 
namely  that  over-reliance  on  taxes  whose  ultimate  burden  is  difficult  to  trace 
is  highly  questionable  from  the  standpoint  of  equity. 

23.  In  taxation,  the  principle  of  equal  treatment  of  equals  has  two  broad 
dimensions.  First,  it  is  a  bulwark  of  protection  against  arbitrary  and  capricious 
treatment  by  tax  authorities.  Second,  it  provides  the  principal  cornerstone  on  the 
basis  of  which  taxes  can  be  justified. 

8 


Chapter  1 :  Paragraphs  20-27 

24.  The  first  dimension  of  the  principle  of  equal  treatment  of  equals  requires 
little  elaboration.  Here  it  serves  as  the  master  guideline  of  tax  legislation  and 
administration.  In  legislation,  the  principle  demands  that  the  over-all  classification 
of  taxpayers  into  categories  be  reasonable  and  just  and  that  all  taxpayers  within  a 
given  category  be  treated  equally.  Thus,  if  it  is  decided  that  a  tax  is  to  be  based  on 
retail  sales,  the  array  of  items  subject  to  tax  must  be  clearly  defined  and  the  rate 
or  rates  must  be  assessed  uniformly.  Then  in  administration,  the  principle  dictates 
both  the  unbiased  handling  of  taxpayer  affairs  on  their  merits  and  the  existence  of 
appropriate  appeal  procedures.  Appeal  must  be  reasonable  in  time  and  in  cost  to 
the  taxpayer,  and  unimpeachable  in  terms  of  the  competence  of  the  persons  decid- 
ing tax  cases,  both  on  questions  of  fact  and  on  questions  of  law.  It  goes  without 
saying  that  while  the  equal  treatment  of  equals  in  legislation  and  administration 
is  easy  to  elaborate  in  theory,  the  application  of  the  principle  can  be  realized  only 
through  constant  public  vigilance  and  governmental  effort. 

25.  The  second  dimension  of  the  principle  of  equal  treatment  of  equals,  which 
involves  the  justification  of  taxes,  is  like  the  first  in  that  it  is  difficult  to  achieve  in 
practice,  but  unfortunately  unlike  the  first  in  that  its  elaboration  in  theory  is  highly 
complex.  We  can  at  least,  however,  begin  on  a  simple  note.  It  is  this:  from  the 
premise  that  equals  should  be  treated  equally,  it  is  generally  conceded  that  unequals 
should  be  treated  unequally.  At  this  point  it  will  be  observed  that  two  time- 
honoured  principles  apply  to  the  unequal  treatment  of  unequals;  namely,  the 
principle  of  benefits  received  and  the  principle  of  ability  to  pay. 

THE  PRINCIPLE  OF  BENEFITS  RECEIVED 

26.  Under  the  principle  of  benefits  received,  equity  is  interpreted  as  requiring 
that  the  burden  of  taxation  be  allocated  among  taxpayers  in  relation  to  the  benefits 
each  derives  from  the  enjoyment  of  public  services.  The  benefit  principle  is 
accordingly  derived  from  a  basic  rule  of  the  private  sector  of  the  economy:  that 
goods  and  services  should  be  paid  for  by  their  users.  Thus  it  provides,  at  least  in 
theory,  a  means  of  determining  the  aggregate  dimensions  of  government  activity 
in  providing  goods  and  services.  The  benefit  principle  was  widely  accepted  by 
political  theorists  in  the  eighteenth  century,  and  supported  by  Adam  Smith  in  his 
Wealth  of  Nations.  It  was  attacked  by  John  Stuart  Mill  a  century  ago  as  imposing 
excessive  burdens  on  the  poor,  but  has  enjoyed  a  vigorous  renaissance  in  recent 
decades. 

27.  Wherever  it  is  possible  to  identify  unmistakably  the  beneficiaries  of  a 
particular  public  service,  the  benefit  principle  leads  not  to  a  tax  but  to  the  charging 
of  a  price  or  fee,  which  makes  the  relationship  between  the  government  and  the 
users  of  its  services  virtually  identical  to  that  between  participants  in  private 
market  transactions.  The  fee  may  cover  the  entire  cost  of  providing  the  service, 
or  alternatively,  where  the  service  is  deemed  to  provide  social  as  well  as  individual 
benefits,  it  may  cover  a  portion  of  the  costs  incurred.  An  example  of  the  latter 
instance  is  found  in  the  charging  of  premiums  for  hospital  care. 


Philosophy  of  Taxation 

28.  In  theory,  the  most  useful  interpretation  of  the  benefit  principle  is  that 
the  cost  of  providing  a  public  service  should  be  allocated  among  individuals  accord- 
ing to  the  marginal  (additional)  benefit  that  each  receives  from  that  service.  A 
willingness  by  the  beneficiaries  to  support  a  new  service  on  this  basis  of  cost 
sharing  will  then  reflect  the  fact  that  they  have  equated  the  marginal  benefit  from 
the  service  in  question  with  the  marginal  sacrifice  involved  in  paying  for  that 
service.  At  this  point  an  optimal  allocation  of  resources  between  the  individual's 
public  and  private  wants  will  have  been  achieved.  In  practice,  it  is  impossible  to 
apply  the  benefit  theory  with  the  above  degree  of  precision  because  marginal  benefit 
to  each  beneficiary  cannot  be  measured  directly.  The  government,  therefore, 
applies  the  principle  in  crude  form  by  allocating  the  total  cost  of  a  service  among 
the  beneficiaries  in  accordance  with  some  arbitrary  criterion — for  example,  real 
property  frontage — in  proportion  to  which  each  individual  is  deemed  to  benefit. 
At  this  point,  of  course,  the  government  is  levying  taxes,  not  charging  fees. 

29.  The  benefit  theory  is  an  appropriate  justification  of  taxation  if  the  principal 
aim  of  the  financial  arrangement  is  to  provide  public  goods  and  services  roughly 
in  accordance  with  the  dictates  of  the  market-place,  and  if  the  government  does 
not  wish  to  modify  the  existing  pattern  of  income  distribution  in  society.  Frequently, 
however,  modification  of  the  existing  distribution  of  income  is  a  particular  objec- 
tive of  government  policy — for  example,  in  the  financing  of  welfare  programs. 
Here  the  benefit  principle  is  clearly  inappropriate.  It  will  likewise  be  inappropriate 
where  society  may  wish  to  subsidize  the  public  treasury  by  increasing  the  cost  of 
certain  activities  that  may  lead  to  abuse  or  inefficiency — the  consumption  of  alco- 
holic beverages,  for  example. 

30.  With  different  degrees  of  emphasis,  the  benefit  principle  can  be  used  to 
justify  a  number  of  taxes  in  whole  or  in  part.  It  is  often  applied  in  defence  of  the 
real  property  tax,  especially  in  so  far  as  this  tax  is  used  to  finance  services  thought 
to  be  more  or  less  directly  related  to  the  ownership  or  occupancy  of  real  property. 
It  forms  the  basis  for  special  assessments  by  municipalities  and  is  frequently  used 
by  various  levels  of  government  in  setting  licence  charges.  An  element  of  "benefit" 
is  even  to  be  found  in  the  personal  income  tax,  as  for  example,  when  questions 
arise  concerning  the  fairest  means  of  taxing  individuals  who  live  in  one  jurisdiction 
but  earn  their  livelihood  in  another.  Again  the  benefit  principle  is  particularly 
relevant  to  taxes  on  gasoline  and  diesel  fuel,  whose  consumption  by  motor  vehicles, 
which  depends  on  speed,  weight  and  distance  travelled,  is  an  excellent  index  of 
demand  for  highway  services. 

31.  It  is  frequently  advocated  that  motor  vehicle  revenues,  because  they  con- 
form so  closely  to  the  benefit  principle,  be  earmarked  and  funded,  that  is  to  say 
that  they  be  segregated  in  a  special  account  distinct  from  the  consolidated  revenue 
fund  and  used  only  to  finance  road  and  highway  expenditure.  The  basic  advantage 
of  earmarking  and  funding  is  that  this  practice  permits  a  close  identification  of 
particular  receipts  and  disbursements,  and  we  recognize  two  general  circumstances 
in  which  it  is  desirable.    The  first  is  where  government  wishes  to  use  the  price 

10 


Chapter  1:  Paragraphs  28-36 

mechanism  in  deciding  how  much  to  charge  for  a  particular  service.  A  munici- 
pality, for  instance,  may  wish  to  make  its  off-street  parking  business  self-support- 
ing, and  here  earmarking  and  funding  will  be  appropriate.  The  second  is  where, 
in  connection  with  particular  social  insurance  programs,  the  government  wishes 
to  emphasize  the  relationship  between  public  benefits  and  the  cost  of  providing 
them.   In  both  circumstances,  the  underlying  benefit  principle  is  readily  apparent. 

32.  But  we  do  not  believe  that  the  presence  of  a  strong  benefit  element,  as  in 
the  case  of  motor  vehicle  revenues,  of  itself  justifies  earmarking  and  funding. 
Indeed,  we  are  of  the  opinion  that  the  disadvantages  of  earmarking  and  funding 
generally  outweigh  the  advantages.  For  one  thing,  this  practice  may  introduce 
undue  rigidity  into  the  over-all  pattern  of  public  finance  by  handcuffing  revenues 
to  a  specific  expenditure  program.  Furthermore,  far  from  ensuring  effective  control 
over  expenditure,  earmarking  and  funding  may  mislead  legislators  if  funded 
revenues  do  not  fully  cover  the  costs  of  a  particular  service.  Revenues  derived 
from  taxes  based  on  the  benefit  principle  provide  a  guide  to  what  is  an  appropriately 
corresponding  level  of  expenditure,  and  the  latter  in  turn  provides  a  general  index 
of  what  the  amount  of  tax  should  be.  The  practice  of  earmarking  and  funding  is 
not  necessary  to  achieve  this  objective. 

33.  We  are  convinced  that  taxation  according  to  the  benefit  principle  has  an 
important  role  in  our  fiscal  system.  Specifically,  we  are  of  the  opinion  that  taxes 
based  on  benefit  are  desirable  first,  when  the  benefits  and  beneficiaries  of  govern- 
ment expenditure  programs  can  be  identified  relatively  clearly;  second,  when  a 
modified  distribution  of  wealth  and  income  is  not  a  policy  objective;  and  third, 
when  the  imposition  of  benefit-related  charges  on  the  users  or  beneficiaries  of  a 
service  will  not  result  in  an  inefficient  use  of  that  service. 

34.  It  is  evident  that  the  above  conditions  restrict  the  application  of  benefit- 
related  taxation  to  a  portion  of  the  revenue-raising  activities  of  government. 
Accordingly,  we  now  turn  to  a  consideration  of  the  principle  of  ability  to  pay,  the 
second  approach  to  achieving  equity  in  taxation,  and  the  major  pillar  of  most 
modern  revenue  systems. 

THE  PRINCIPLE  OF  ABILITY  TO  PAY 

35.  Under  the  principle  of  ability  to  pay,  equity  requires  the  equal  treatment 
of  persons  possessing  the  same  capacity  to  pay  taxes.  Ability  to  pay  is  appropriate 
for  financing  that  great  portion  of  government  expenditure  where  it  is  either 
impossible  or  inappropriate  to  allocate  cost  among  taxpayers  in  accordance  with 
benefits  received.  The  application  of  the  ability  principle,  however,  requires 
agreement  on  some  generally  accepted  criterion  or  criteria  by  which  capacity  to 
pay  taxes  may  be  measured. 

36.  Under  the  early  versions  of  the  ability-to-pay  principle,  in  sixteenth- 
century  Europe  and  later  in  North  America,  wealth  or  property  was  considered 
the  most  appropriate  index  of  tax-paying  capacity.   A  Uttle  later,  consumption  or 

11 


Philosophy  of  Taxation 

spending  was  singled  out  as  most  suitable.  Thus  Thomas  Hobbes,  the  seventeenth- 
century  English  philosopher,  stated  that  equity  required  that  people  be  taxed  on  the 
basis  of  what  they  used  up  of  their  country's  product,  not  on  the  basis  of  what  they 
contributed  to  it.  In  our  present  generation,  Mr.  Nicholas  Kaldor  of  Cambridge 
University  is  perhaps  the  foremost  exponent  of  an  expenditure  tax,  regarding  con- 
sumption as  an  equitable  criterion  of  ability  to  pay.-  As  a  matter  of  general 
practice,  with  the  increase  in  industrialization  of  the  past  century,  income  has 
become  widely  regarded  as  the  best  index  of  tax-paying  capacity. 

37.  The  case  for  income  as  a  better  index  of  ability  to  pay  than  either  con- 
sumption or  wealth  rests  on  the  fact  that  income  is  a  more  comprehensive  index 
than  the  other  two.  Income,  after  all,  comprises  both  consumption  and  saving,  or 
increases  in  wealth,  during  a  given  time  period.  Against  this  it  can  be  argued 
that  income  is  inferior  to  consumption  precisely  because  it  is  too  comprehensive. 
Because  an  income  tax  applies  to  saving,  it  reduces  the  capital  which  an  individual 
can  invest,  and  the  effect  is  compounded  when,  at  a  later  period  of  time,  the  same 
individual  will  be  taxed  again  on  the  interest  income  from  his  reduced  investment. 
But  this  viewpoint  is  far  from  unassailable.  The  counter-argument  is  that  interest 
on  accumulation  is  an  additional  accretion  to  income  and  that  the  tax  thereon  is 
therefore  a  new  tax  on  new  income.  In  the  words  of  a  leading  contemporary 
authority,  "If  this  view  is  taken,  it  is  not  the  income  tax  that  involves  'double 
taxation',  but  the  consumption  tax  that  involves  undertaxation  of  the  saver."^  It 
seems  fair  to  conclude  that  the  extent  to  which  society  taxes  consumption  as 
opposed  to  income  will  be  a  function  of  that  society's  desire  to  encourage  saving. 

38.  By  contrast  to  wealth,  the  taxation  of  income  recommends  itself  again 
in  that  income  is  more  universal  than  wealth  and  a  better  index  of  an  individual's 
standard  of  living.  Many  Canadian  families  enjoy  relatively  high  incomes  and 
consequently  high  living  standards,  and  yet  possess  relatively  little  wealth.  On  the 
other  hand  there  are  many  others,  especially  older  persons  owning  homes, 
businesses  or  farms,  who  may  possess  considerable  amounts  of  wealth  but  rela- 
tively little  income  and  a  very  modest  standard  of  living.  The  taxation  of  wealth 
can  none  the  less  be  viewed  as  a  useful,  indeed  necessary,  supplement  to  the  taxa- 
tion of  income.  Income  by  definition  fails  to  take  into  account  changes  in  the 
capital  value  of  savings,  and  hence  does  not  fully  reflect  changes  in  an  individual's 
economic  position  from  time  to  time.  It  is  thus  deemed  desirable  in  most  countries 
to  tax  wealth — for  example,  when  increases  in  the  value  of  assets  are  realized 
through  sale,  by  means  of  a  capital  gains  tax,  or,  when  assets  change  hands 
through  gifts  or  successions,  by  means  of  gift  and  death  taxes. 

39.  We  concur  in  the  widely  accepted  practice  that  takes  income  as  the  prime 
index  of  tax-paying  capacity.  At  the  same  time,  and  for  the  reasons  discussed 
above,  we  believe  that  wealth  and  consumption  must  be  essential  components  of 
a  tax  system  based  on  a  notion  of  balanced  tax-paying  capacity.  In  this  connection 


''See  Nicholas  Kaldor,  An  Expenditure  Tax,  London:  George  Allen  &  Unwin,  Ltd.,  1955. 
•■"Richard  A.  Musgrave,  The  Theory  of  Public  Finance,  New  York:  McGraw-Hill  Book 
Company,  1959,  p.  162. 

12 


Chapter  1 :  Paragraphs  37-43 

we  wish  to  stress  that  the  allocation  of  the  tax  burden  among  individuals  or 
families  is  accomplished  through  the  aggregate  effect  of  all  taxes  taken  together 
and  not  by  any  one  tax.  Furthermore,  as  will  be  demonstrated  in  a  later  chapter, 
to  produce  over-all  equity,  government  fiscal  operations  must  take  into  account  the 
differential  impact  of  public  expenditures  on  individual  incomes  as  well  as  the 
impact  of  taxes. 

40.  It  has  been  only  in  the  twentieth  century  that  broad  support  has  developed 
for  the  idea  that  to  conform  to  ability  to  pay,  a  tax  system  must  be  progressive. 
Individual  taxes  in  fact  differ  greatly  in  the  degree  to  which  they  conform  to  this 
notion,  but  the  idea  in  question  is  most  effectively  embodied  today  in  the  personal 
income  tax.  The  personal  income  tax  generally  incorporates  basic  exemptions  that 
recognize  minimum  income  standards  below  which  no  tax  should  be  levied.  These 
exemptions  can  be  tailored  to  recognize  the  need  for  minimal  levels  of  income  and 
the  existence  of  different  family  responsibilities  for  maintaining  dependants. 
Above  the  basic  exemption  level,  rates  of  personal  income  tax  can  be  made  to 
vary  in  increasing  proportion  as  the  level  of  income  rises.  Thus  it  is  that  the 
personal  income  tax  is  widely  acclaimed  as  the  tax  most  in  accord  with  the 
principle  of  ability  to  pay. 

41.  While  the  personal  income  tax  may  indeed  be  the  most  equitable  tax  in 
terms  of  tax-paying  capacity,  it  must  be  emphasized  that  this  is  far  more  a  con- 
clusion of  social  judgment  than  of  scientific  principle.  Admittedly,  a  degree  of 
support  for  taxation  at  progressive  rates  can  be  drawn  from  the  economist's  law 
of  diminishing  marginal  utility.  The  most  concise  statement  of  this  law  is  probably 
that  of  the  celebrated  Alfred  Marshall,  who,  near  the  turn  of  the  century,  noted 
that  "the  marginal  utility  of  a  thing  to  anyone  diminishes  with  every  increase 
in  the  amount  of  it  he  already  has."'*  In  other  words,  the  increased  satisfaction 
(marginal  utility)  that  any  individual  obtains  from  owning  or  consuming  each 
additional  unit  of  any  commodity  or  service  diminishes  according  to  the  number  of 
units  that  he  already  owns  or  has  consumed. 

42.  The  operation  of  the  law  of  diminishing  marginal  utility  is  readily  evident 
and  a  matter  of  common  sense.  In  the  case  of  milkshakes  and  hot  dogs,  for 
example,  the  diminishing  utility  of  consuming  successive  units  within  a  given  time 
period  is  clearly  apparent,  for  the  hmited  capacity  of  the  human  stomach  causes 
the  law  to  operate  quickly.  With  other  items  of  consumption,  and  particularly  with 
intangibles  such  as  travel  and  education,  many  successive  units  can  be  consumed 
over  a  long  time  period  before  the  law  will  gradually  begin  to  assert  itself.  But 
assert  itself  it  will;  among  academics,  for  instance,  a  second  earned  Ph.D.  is  a  rarity. 

43.  In  the  realm  of  taxation,  the  law  of  diminishing  marginal  utility  is 
relevant  in  so  far  as  it  applies  to  successive  marginal  units  of  income.  Income  is 
either  consumed  or  saved,  and  saving  can  be  defined  as  the  forgoing  of  present 
consumption.    Accordingly,  it  can  be  argued  that  since  all  income  is  eventually 


*Alfred   Marshall,  Principle   of  Economics,   8th  edition,  New   York:    The    Macmillan 
Company,  1920,  p.  93. 

13 


Philosophy  of  Taxation 

exchanged  for  goods  and  services,  the  marginal  utility  of  income  will  decline, 
reflecting  the  decreasing  marginal  utility  of  these  goods  and  services.  If  this  is  so, 
it  follows  that  an  individual  will  sacrifice  less  of  his  well-being  (utility)  in  paying 
a  tax  of  1  per  cent  on  an  income  of,  let  us  say,  $10,000  than  on  an  income  of 
$5,000.  Hence  if  ability  to  pay  is  regarded  as  equality  of  sacrifice,  a  taxpayer's 
contribution  should  vary  more  than  proportionately  as  his  income  changes. 

44.  At  least  two  noteworthy  criticisms  can  be  directed  against  linking  progres- 
sive taxation  with  the  diminishing  marginal  utility  of  income.  The  first  is  that  such 
a  linkage  assumes  that  the  utility  of  the  successive  dollars  of  a  given  income  declines 
equally  for  all,  whereas  in  fact  there  exist  great  differences  in  the  satisfaction 
derived  by  different  individuals  from  succeeding  units  of  income.  The  second  is 
that  the  actual  rate  at  which  the  marginal  utility  of  income  declines  cannot  be 
known  and  hence  diminishing  utility  provides  no  guide  as  to  what  is  an  appropriate 
rate  of  tax  progression. 

45.  The  first  criticism  is  entirely  valid,  but  in  our  view  it  in  no  way  contra- 
dicts the  proposition  that  the  tax-paying  capacity  of  an  individual  increases  faster 
than  his  income,  and  that  society  is  therefore  entitled  to  make  a  judgment  on  this 
basis.  In  the  words  of  Dr.  Richard  Goode  of  the  Brookings  Institution,  such  an 
assertion  has  appeal 

because  it  is  plausible  to  suppose  that  people  first  satisfy  their  most  urgent 
needs  and  then  use  additional  income  to  meet  less  urgent  wants  and  because, 
in  civilized  communities,  public  or  private  assistance  is  given  to  those  who  lack 
the  means  to  provide  for  themselves  the  items  that  are  customarily  bought  with 
small  incomes.  It  is  widely  agreed,  even  by  severe  critics  of  extensive  progres- 
sion, that  people  below  a  certain  level  of  poverty  should  not  be  expected  to 
pay  taxes.  Acceptance  of  a  personal  exemption  necessarily  implies  endorse- 
ment of  at  least  a  limited  degree  of  progression,  since  tax  liability  will  rise 
faster  than  income  immediately  above  the  exemption,  even  if  rates  are  not 
graduated.  In  my  judgment,  the  reasoning  that  approves  this  level  of  pro- 
gression can  also  justify  much  wider  progressivity.  To  deny  this  would  imply 
that  there  is  a  sharp  discontinuity  in  the  sacrifices  made  in  paying  taxes  or  in 
the  social  importance  of  successive  increments  of  income,  consumption,  or 
wealth.  It  seems  more  plausible  to  suppose  that  the  private  and  social 
importance  of  additional  units  diminishes  gradually  over  a  very  wide  range. '^ 

46.  We  likewise  support  the  second  assertion  that  the  slope  of  marginal  income 
utility  schedules  cannot  be  known.  We  would  point  out  that  it  is  simply  impossible 
to  "measure"  utility  in  an  absolute  sense,  in  which  case  it  becomes  obvious  that 
the  notion  of  diminishing  marginal  utility  provides  no  guide  to  an  appropriate 
degree  of  rate  progressivity.  We  accept  this  as  a  fact.  But  surely  this  notion  need 
not  have  mathematical  precision  to  support  the  principle  of  a  progressive  income 
tax.  To  quote  Dr.  Goode  once  more. 

If  this  seems  distressingly  imprecise,  it  is  because  ability  to  pay  is  being 
regarded  as  the  name  of  a  numerical  formula  rather  than  a  term  of  ethics  or 
politics,  as  it  should  be.    Ability  to  pay  is  no  more  imprecise  than  concepts 


'Richard  Goode,  The  Individual  Income  Tax,  Washington,  D.C.:  The  Brookings  Insti- 
tution, 1964,  pp.  18-19. 

14 


Chapter  1 :  Paragraphs  44-49i 

such  as  the  national  interest,  general  welfare,  due  process  of  law,  morality  and 
duty.  It  is  as  susceptible  of  objective  valuation  as  are  intelligence,  social 
adjustment,  prudence,  and  many  other  personal  characteristics.^ 

47.  While  we  strongly  support  the  principle  of  ability  to  pay  as  a  cornerstone 
of  sound  taxation  and  believe  that  income  provides  the  most  reliable  but  by  no 
means  sole  index  of  tax-paying  capacity,  we  readily  admit  that  the  principle  and 
the  so-called  "law"  from  which  it  is  often  derived  provide  no  guide  as  to  the  most 
appropriate  rate  of  progression.  The  ultimate  sanction  for  any  given  pattern  of 
tax  progression  is  the  prevailing  consensus  of  ethical  judgment  as  to  what  con- 
stitutes a  socially  desirable  distribution  of  the  nation's  income  and  wealth.  Without 
undertaking  to  probe  the  depths  of  this  consensus,  we  think  it  appropriate  at  this 
juncture  to  suggest  two  guidelines  that  we  believe  are  important  considerations  on 
making  social  judgments  on  progressivity.  The  first  is  that  the  concept  of  ability 
to  pay,  rather  than  dictating  the  progressivity  of  any  given  tax,  embodies  instead 
the  more  general  notion  that  the  tax  system  should  be  moderately  progressive  as 
a  whole.  The  second  is  that  government  expenditures,  which  themselves  affect 
the  relative  position  of  individuals,  should  be  considered  along  with  taxes  in 
determining  what  constitutes  over-all  equity. 

48.  We  attempt  to  show  in  a  later  chapter  that  different  taxes  place  rather 
different  burdens  on  individuals  and  families  with  different  levels  of  income.  Thus 
property  taxes,  motor  vehicle  fuel  taxes  and  retail  taxes,  to  take  but  a  few 
examples,  each  absorb  rather  different  proportions  of  family  income,  depending  on 
the  size  of  that  income.  Such  taxes,  of  course,  cannot  take  into  account  varying 
personal  and  financial  circumstances.  This  suggests  to  us  that  the  personal  income 
tax,  which  can  be  tailored  to  take  relatively  precise  account  of  such  circumstances, 
has  a  particularly  critical  role  in  helping  to  achieve  equity  and  that  the  burden  of 
the  other  taxes  on  individuals  and  families  provides  a  rough  but  useful  guide  to  the 
desirable  degree  of  progressivity  in  personal  income  tax  rates. 

49.  A  truly  comprehensive  guide  to  the  setting  of  personal  income  tax  rates 
will  take  into  account  the  impact  on  the  individual  of  government  expenditure  as 
well  as  of  other  taxes.  It  is  significant  that  progressivity  first  received  great  emphasis 
some  decades  ago  when  it  was  thought  that  an  equitable  distribution  of  income 
should  be  accomplished  almost  entirely  through  the  tax  mechanism.  However, 
during  the  last  quarter-century,  both  in  Canada  and  elsewhere,  the  distribution 
of  income  has  been  greatly  affected  through  the  expenditure  side  of  fiscal  opera- 
tions, and  in  particular  through  government  transfer  payments  such  as  family 
allowances,  unemployment  insurance  and  old  age  pensions.  This  range  of  activity 
has  been  continuously  broadened  and,  in  addition,  government  spending  on  goods 
and  services  further  alters  the  distribution  of  income.  Under  these  circumstances, 
to  ignore  the  effects  of  government  spending  will  be  to  distort  seriously  the 
distribution  of  income  on  which  judgments  of  tax  progressivity  should  be  made. 
Indeed,  when  the  impact  of  all  government  fiscal  operations — that  is  to  say,  taxes 
and  expenditures — on  the  individual  are  taken  into  account,  it  may  well  be  that 

Hbid,  p.  19. 

15 


Philosophy  of  Taxation 

considerations  of  equity  will  call  for  personal  income  tax  rates  somewhat  more 
moderately  progressive  than  at  present. 

50.  In  closing  our  discussion  of  equity  in  taxation,  we  wish  to  emphasize  two 
points.  The  first  is  that  whether  it  is  embodied  in  the  principle  of  benefits  received 
or  in  that  of  ability  to  pay,  equity  relates  solely  to  the  individual  or  family  and  has 
no  meaning  except  with  regard  to  those  persons  on  whom  the  burden  of  taxation 
ultimately  falls.  In  particular,  equity  provides  no  basis  for  the  taxation  of  corporate 
income,  the  rationale  for  which  is  discussed  at  a  later  stage  of  this  Report.  Our 
second  point  is  that  no  tax  system  can  be  considered  equitable  unless  it  rests  in 
part  both  on  ability  to  pay  and  on  benefits  received.  Benefits  received  is  a  key 
element  in  determining  the  optimum  total  of  taxation,  and  therefore  the  appropriate 
distribution  of  resources  between  public  and  private  uses.  Ability  to  pay,  on  the 
other  hand,  in  taking  into  account  the  equitable  distribution  of  income,  is  an 
indispensable  guide  to  the  proper  allocation  of  the  burden  of  financing  government. 

OTHER  PRINCIPLES  OF  TAXATION 

51.  Equity  is  the  prime,  but  by  no  means  the  sole,  characteristic  of  a  good 
tax  system.  After  due  consideration,  we  have  selected  no  fewer  than  nine 
principles  which,  together  with  equity,  should  form  the  basis  of  a  sound  revenue 
structure.  Some  of  these  are  derived  from  considerations  of  equity,  others  are 
prompted  by  the  need  for  efficiency.  We  enumerate  them  here  for  the  sake  of 
convenience  and  will  proceed  to  discuss  them  in  turn.    They  are: 

1 .  adequacy, 

2.  flexibility, 

3.  elasticity, 

4.  balance, 

5.  neutrality, 

6.  certainty, 

7.  simplicity, 

8.  convenience,  and 

9.  economy  of  collection  and  compliance. 

ADEQUACY 

52.  This  principle  requires  virtually  no  explanation.  It  is  a  self-evident 
proposition  that  to  be  satisfactory,  a  tax  system  must  be  capable  of  providing  the 
flow  of  funds  that  a  government  deems  appropriate  in  any  given  period.  We  note, 
however,  that  the  principle  of  adequacy  can  become  highly  relevant  when  the 
relative  merits  of  grants  and  taxes  are  discussed  in  connection  with  provincial 
and  municipal  revenue  systems.  This  matter  will  occupy  our  attention  in  the 
next  chapter. 

FLEXIBILITY 

53.  By  flexibility  is  meant  that  a  tax  system  should  be  so  constituted  that 
government,  by  discretionary  action,  can  readily  increase  or  decrease  the  flow 

16 


Chapter  1 :  Paragraphs  50-56 

of  tax  funds  in  response  to  changing  circumstances,  which  can  stem  either  from 
considerations  of  expenditure  requirements  or  of  economic  poUcy.  Obviously, 
some  taxes,  such  as  those  on  property  and  on  personal  income,  are  more  flexible 
than  others,  in  that  rate  alterations  can  be  graded  so  as  to  accommodate  small 
as  well  as  large  changes  in  revenue  requirements.  The  principle  of  flexibility  can 
thus  be  deemed  to  be  satisfied  if  a  revenue  system  is  comprised  in  part  of  flexible 
taxes. 

ELASTICITY 

54.  The  principle  of  elasticity  is  closely  related  to  those  of  adequacy  and 
flexibility.  This  principle  requires  that  a  revenue  system  be  composed  in  part  of 
taxes  whose  yields  respond  closely  to  changing  economic  circumstances  without 
deliberate  changes  in  rates.  It  is  important  that  the  principle  be  fulfilled  for  two 
reasons.  First,  elasticity  enables  governments  to  meet  rising  service  demands 
occasioned  by  economic  growth  without  the  disturbance  of  frequent  rate  changes. 
Second,  elastic  tax  yields  are  an  important  adjunct  of  fiscal  policy  in  that  they 
can  serve  as  automatic  stabilizers,  leaving  a  greater  proportion  of  income  in 
the  private  sector  in  times  of  adversity  and  dampening  inflationary  pressures  in 
times  of  prosperity. 

BALANCE 

55.  This  principle  is  to  be  found  in  certain  textbooks  under  such  names  as 
"multiplicity"  or  "plurality",  but  we  have  chosen  the  term  "balance"  in  order  to 
emphasize  the  kind  of  plurality  that  a  tax  system  should  possess.  The  need  for  a 
balanced  plurality  of  taxes  is  grounded  partly  in  the  requirements  of  flexibility 
and  elasticity,  partly  in  equity,  and  partly  in  administrative  considerations.  As  to 
flexibility  and  elasticity,  it  is  readily  apparent  that  some  taxes  are  more  flexible, 
others  more  elastic.  Thus  the  property  tax  is  relatively  unresponsive  to  economic 
change  but  highly  flexible,  whereas  consumption  taxes  are  rather  more  elastic  but 
relatively  inflexible.  A  tax  system  should  therefore  have  a  sufficient  multiplicity 
of  taxes  to  take  account  of  these  characteristics.  In  the  domain  of  equity,  if  a 
tax  system  is  to  conform  to  the  basic  rule  of  equal  treatment  of  equals,  it  must 
not  only  be  able  to  take  differing  individual  situations  into  account  but  also  be 
virtually  foolproof  in  terms  of  evasion.  If  we  may  quote  the  Right  Honourable  Hugh 
Dalton,  a  former  ChanceUor  of  the  Exchequer  of  the  United  Kingdom, 

Anomalies  as  between  persons,  which  are  liable  to  arise  under  a  single  tax, 
are  liable  to  be  corrected  under  a  multiplicity  of  taxes.  And  evasions,  which 
may  be  comparatively  easy  under  a  single  tax,  are  more  readily  detected  under 
the  check  and  counter-check  which  a  multiple  tax  system  may  provide.  Thus 
valuations  for  death  duties  and  the  previous  income  tax  returns  of  the  deceased 
may  be  checked  against  one  another.' 

56.  Multiplicity,  then,  is  an  important  key  to  elasticity,  flexibility  and  equity. 
But  it  is  not  an  end  in  itself.    For  one  thing,  the  number  of  taxes  that  reflect 


^Hugh  Dalton,  Principles  of  Public  Finance,  4th  edition,  London:   Routledge  &  Kegan 
Paul  Ltd.,  1954,  p.  31. 

17 


Philosophy  of  Taxation 

elasticity,  flexibility  and  equity  is  limited.  Furthermore,  to  quote  Mr.  Dalton 
again, 

.  .  .  though  a  multiple  tax  system  is  generally  preferable  to  a  single  tax  system, 
too  great  a  multiplicity  is  not  desirable.  Advocates  of  "broadening  the  basis 
of  taxation"  are  to  be  distrusted.  Of  this  fellowship  was  [one]  who  said,  "if 
I  were  to  define  a  good  system  of  taxation,  it  should  be  that  of  bearing  lightly 
on  an  infinite  number  of  points,  heavily  on  none."  But  there  is  not  necessarily 
any  less  total  pressure  under  such  a  system  for,  as  mathematicians  know,  the 
sum  of  an  infinitely  large  number  of  infinitely  small  weights  may  be  greater 
than  a  single  moderate  weight.  Moreover,  a  large  number  of  taxes,  however 
small,  usually  involves  a  large  cost  and  a  large  amount  of  vexation  in  collection.* 

To  this  we  wish  only  to  add  the  thought  that  too  great  a  multiplicity  of  taxes 
may  dissipate  altogether  taxpayer  consciousness  of  the  cost  of  government,  con- 
sciousness that  is  certainly  desirable  in  a  constitutional  democracy.  Thus  we 
subscribe  only  to  that  multiplicity  of  taxes  consistent  with  flexibility,  elasticity, 
equity  and  sound  administration — in  short,  to  a  principle  of  balance. 

NEUTRALITY 

57.  The  principle  of  neutrality  is  directly  related  to  the  objective  of  efliciency 
in  the  use  of  the  human  and  material  resources  of  society.  We  do  not  suggest 
that,  in  order  to  be  neutral,  a  fiscal  system  must  exert  no  influence  on  the  economic 
behaviour  of  persons  or  businesses.  When  the  fiscal  operations  of  all  levels  of 
government  in  Canada  involve,  as  they  do,  almost  one-third  of  gross  national 
product,  it  is  clear  that  no  such  thing  is  possible.  Our  approach  to  neutraUty  is 
rather  in  terms  of  applying  the  rule  of  least  price  distortion  in  the  choice  of  taxes. 
If  one  assumes  that  the  pattern  of  relative  prices  determined  by  competitive  market 
forces  tends  to  encourage  the  most  efficient  allocation  of  the  nation's  resources, 
then  to  the  extent  that  a  tax  system  minimizes  its  distortion  of  relative  prices,  it 
minimizes  its  interference  with  productive  efficiency.  An  important  implication 
follows,  namely  that  the  more  general  a  tax,  the  less  it  will  normally  interfere  with 
individual  choices  on  the  part  of  producers,  resource  owners  and  consumers.  From 
this  point  of  view,  such  general  taxes  as  those  on  income  and  retail  sales  are  to 
be  preferred  to  selective  excise  taxes  applied  to  a  narrow  range  of  commodities. 

58.  Understood  in  terms  of  least  price  distortion,  the  principle  of  neutrality 
is  violated  if  consumers  are  taxed  on  their  expenditures  for  goods  but  not  for 
services.  The  principle  is  likewise  violated  if  governments  provide  tax  concessions 
in  order  to  induce  particular  firms  or  industries  to  locate  in  areas  where,  in  terms 
of  the  most  efficient  use  of  resources,  they  would  not  otherwise  go.  In  its  broad 
context,  however,  the  efficient  use  of  resources  involves  not  only  the  private 
costs  incurred  by  a  firm  but  also  the  social  costs  arising  from  its  operation  in  a 
particular  location.  Again,  neutrality  will  be  violated  where  the  revenue  system 
imposes  heavier  taxes  on  some  legal  forms  of  business  organization  than  on 
others.  To  be  neutral,  the  tax  system  should  provide  similar  treatment  for  indi- 
vidual proprietors,  partnerships,  co-operatives  and  all  forms  of  corporate  enterprise. 

"Ibid.,  p.  32. 

18 


Chapter  1 :  Paragraphs  57-62 

We  are,  of  course,  fully  aware  of  the  enormous  practical  difficulties  involved  in 
providing  such  neutral  treatment. 

59.  We  do  not  wish  to  argue  that  neutrality  is  a  principle  of  taxation  that 
should  be  followed  under  any  and  all  circumstances.  It  is  appropriate  only  when 
economic  efficiency  is  a  prime  criterion  of  policy.  On  frequent  occasions,  govern- 
ments are  legitimately  more  concerned  with  other  goals  and  will  consciously  depart 
from  neutrality  in  order  to  further  these  objectives.  What  should  be  recognized, 
however,  is  that  where  tax  neutrality  is  abandoned,  the  efficient  allocation  of 
resources,  in  the  short  run  at  least,  will  be  impeded. 

CERTAINTY 

60.  The  principle  of  certainty  as  to  the  time,  manner  and  amount  of  payment 
of  tax  has  been  advocated  for  centuries.  Adam  Smith  regarded  a  small  degree 
of  uncertainty  as  a  much  greater  evil  than  "a  very  considerable  degree  of 
inequality'V  in  that  it  subjected  the  taxpayer  to  the  arbitrary  decisions  of  the 
authorities.  A  further  argument  for  certainty  is  the  desirability,  in  an  era  of  high 
government  expenditure,  that  the  citizen  be  well  informed  of  his  tax  burden  so 
that  he  may  relate  it  to  the  benefits  he  derives  from  public  services.  If  the  individual 
is  not  well  informed,  he  may  make  decisions  about  government  spending  that  might 
have  been  different  had  he  been  aware  of  the  facts.  A  particular  risk  is  that  being 
only  dimly  aware  of  his  total  tax  burden,  he  will  underestimate  the  cost  of  the 
public  services  with  which  he  is  provided.  This  is  particularly  Ukely  where  many 
of  his  taxes  are  hidden  in  the  prices  of  the  goods  and  services  he  purchases, 
rather  than  imposed  upon  him  directly. 

61.  If  the  principle  of  certainty  is  vaUd,  and  we  beUeve  that  it  is,  then  those 
direct  taxes  that  cannot  be  shifted,  or  that  can  be  shifted  only  to  a  limited  degree, 
are  superior  to  any  taxes  that  can  be  hidden  or  easily  shifted.  On  this  basis,  the 
personal  income  tax  is  superior  to  corporation  income  tax  which  sooner  or  later 
must  be  borne  by  individuals  as  consumers,  shareholders  or  employees.  Similarly, 
a  visible  retail  sales  tax  is  superior  to  a  consumption  tax  levied  at  the  manufacturer's 
level.  Again,  as  it  affects  the  relative  merits  of  subsidies  or  tax  concessions  as  forms 
of  government  financial  assistance,  the  principle  of  certainty  favours  subsidies, 
for  their  costs  are  more  readily  ascertainable  to  government  and  public  alike  than 
are  the  costs  of  tax  concessions  or  exemptions. 

62.  Finally,  the  principle  of  certainty  should  apply  with  force  to  the  content 
of  tax  statutes.  At  the  very  least,  no  tax  law  should  be  written  in  such  a  way 
that  it  contains  provisions  that  the  government  either  cannot  or  will  not  enforce 
effectively.  An  obvious  example  of  such  a  provision  can  be  found  in  the  Ontario 
Retail  Sales  Tax  Act  which  stipulates  that  residents  of  Ontario  are  liable  for  sales 
tax  on  goods  bought  outside  but  transported  into  the  province  for  their  use.  To 
the  extent  that  such  a  requirement  is  known  to  be  the  law  but  is  not  enforced,  the 


®Adam  Smith,  The  Wealth  of  Nations,  Modern  Library  edition.  New  York:   Random 
House,  1937,  p.  778. 

19 


Philosophy  of  Taxation 

reputation  of  the  government  as  a  law-maker,  to  say  nothing  of  respect  for  the 
law  itself,  is  imperceptibly  lowered  in  the  public  esteem.  The  principle  of  certainty 
demands  statutes  that  are  at  once  enforceable  and  enforced. 

SIMPLICITY 

63.  We  wish  to  comment  only  briefly  on  the  relation  between  certainty  and 
simplicity.  The  principle  of  simplicity  will  lend  strong  support  to  certainty  pro- 
vided it  is  applied  with  care.  The  point  is,  of  course,  that  indiscriminate  striving 
for  simplicity  will  yield  statutes  that  leave  too  much  unsaid  and  hence  that  can 
only  be  applied  with  a  wide  scope  for  administrative  discretion — discretion  that 
will  unduly  impinge  on  certainty.  Again,  undue  simplicity  may  make  it  impossible 
to  recognize  the  varying  circumstances  of  particular  taxpayers.  Hence  the  principle 
of  simplicity  must  be  considered  as  dictating  the  greatest  clarity  within  the  limits 
set  by  certainty  and  equity.  It  should  be  understood  that  after  every  effort  has 
been  made  to  apply  the  principle  of  simplicity  in  the  sense  indicated  above,  certain 
taxes,  notably  those  on  personal  and  corporate  income,  will  be  embodied  in 
statutes  that  are  irreducibly  but  still  appreciably  complex. 

CONVENIENCE 

64.  The  principle  of  convenience  is  highly  significant  in  relation  to  the  time, 
place  and  manner  in  which  a  taxpayer  is  called  upon  to  discharge  his  obligations. 
It  is  in  accordance  with  this  principle  that  municipaUties  have  developed  instal- 
ment systems  for  the  payment  of  property  taxes  and  have,  in  some  instances, 
permitted  payment  through  chartered  banks  and  other  specified  places  of  business. 
The  principle  of  convenience  is  not  simply  a  matter  of  good  public  relations. 
Observance  of  this  principle  redounds  to  the  direct  advantage  of  government  by 
simplifying  compliance  and  by  reducing  costs.  With  regard  to  the  latter,  there 
can  be  no  doubt  that  the  deduction  of  income  tax  at  the  source,  a  practice  intro- 
duced by  the  Dominion  during  World  War  II,  has  greatly  simplified  government 
fiscal  operations  by  increasing  the  speed  of  cash  flows  and  hence  reducing  the 
need  for  short-term  borrowing. 

ECONOMY  OF  COLLECTION  AND  COMPLIANCE 

65.  The  principle  of  economy  applies  both  to  the  costs  incurred  by  government 
in  collecting  taxes  and  to  those  incurred  by  the  taxpayer  in  complying  with  his 
tax  obligations.  With  regard  to  compliance,  we  have  later  in  this  Report  devoted 
considerable  effort  to  devising  appeals  procedures  that  are  within  the  financial 
means  of  all  taxpayers.  We  wish  to  point  out,  however,  that  the  principle  of 
economy,  especially  in  relation  to  the  costs  incurred  by  government,  dictates  not 
the  lowest  possible  cost  but  the  lowest  cost  consistent  with  equity  and  effective 
enforcement.  Thus  it  is  blatantly  false  economy  for  governments  to  employ 
unqualified  assessors  at  rock-bottom  rates  of  remuneration.  Such  practices  can 
result  only  in  inefficiency,  discrimination,  and  multiplying  appeals  and  hence 
increasing  the  cost  of  taxpayer  compliance.  Properly  understood,  the  principle 
of  economy  requires  the  employment  of  competent  public  servants  in  sufficient 
numbers. 

20 


Chapter  1 :  Paragraphs  63-69 

CONFLICTS  OF  TAX  PRINCIPLES 

66.  It  is  the  better  part  of  wisdom  to  recognize  that  among  the  many  tax 
principles  that  we  have  outlined  there  exist  numerous  occasions  for  conflict. 
Decisions  concerning  the  most  appropriate  mix  of  taxes  will  accordingly  require 
some  consensus  as  to  which  principles  should  be  given  priority,  a  consensus  that 
even  among  responsible  and  reasonable  people  may  be  difficult  to  formulate. 
Thus  thorny  problems  may  arise  because  of  differing  interpretations  of  the  principle 
of  ability  to  pay,  or  because  this  principle  conflicts  with  benefits  received  or  with 
neutrality  or  with  simplicity  or  with  economy  of  collection  and  compliance.  Then 
too,  it  may  be  that  convenience  or  the  reasonable  opportunity  to  appeal — an 
essential  aspect  of  equity- — conflicts  with  economy.  Whatever  the  nature  of  the 
conflict,  we  wish  to  stress  that  among  all  the  principles  that  we  have  discussed, 
those  relating  to  equity  are  of  fundamental  importance  in  the  formulation  of  tax 
policy.  This  is  by  no  means  to  deny  that  in  specific  circumstances  equity  may 
legitimately  be  subordinated  to  other  principles,  but  where  such  is  argued,  we 
place  the  burden  of  proof  squarely  on  the  proponents  of  the  case. 

TAX  PRINCIPLES  AND  SOCIAL  POLICY 

67.  We  wish  to  close  this  chapter  by  noting  that  there  wiU  be  instances 
where  certain  tax  practices  depart  from  principles  not  because  of  conflict  between 
the  principles  but  because  certain  generally  accepted  goals  of  social  policy  are 
held  to  override  the  principles.  To  cite  but  three  well-known  examples,  let  us 
briefly  examine  the  tax  treatment  of  alcohol  and  tobacco,  the  exemption  of 
churches  and  charitable  organizations  from  property  tax,  and  tax  discrimination 
based  on  location. 

68.  In  all  countries  whose  revenue  systems  we  have  studied,  alcohol  and 
tobacco  are  taxed  more  heavily  than  other  foods  and  beverages.  This  is  a  viola- 
tion of  the  principle  of  neutrality,  sanctioned  historically  in  part  by  the  widespread 
belief  that  such  commodities  are  luxuries  whose  consumption,  within  limits,  should 
be  discouraged.  We  are  not  convinced  that  many  governments  have  seriously 
sought  to  attain  sumptuary  objectives  of  this  kind  by  taxation,  or  that  where  they 
have,  the  pricing  mechanism  represents  the  most  appropriate  or  effective  means 
of  achieving  these  objectives.  Stronger  justification  for  the  relatively  high  taxation 
of  these  products  undoubtedly  rests  on  the  fact  that  their  heavy  consumption  by 
many  individuals  imposes  substantial  costs  on  society.  But  the  very  high  taxation 
of  alcohol  and  tobacco  in  many  jurisdictions  must  ultimately  rest  on  social  policy 
and  consensus. 

69.  The  exemption  of  churches  and  charitable  organizations  from  real  property 
taxes — a  common  practice  in  Canada,  the  United  States  and  other  countries — 
violates  the  principles  of  benefits  received,  equal  treatment  of  equals,  and  neutrality. 
The  social  policy  underlying  such  exemptions  and  other  preferential  treatment  may 
be  defended  in  terms  of  the  valuable  contributions  that  these  institutions  make  to 
their  supporters  and  to  society  generally,  and  because  of  the  difficulty  of  providing 
support  for  churches  through  direct  subsidy. 

21 


Philosophy  of  Taxation 

70.  Social  policy  frequently  finds  expression  in  tax  discrimination  on  the 
basis  of  the  location  of  the  taxpayer.  Such  discrimination  clearly  violates  the 
principle  of  equal  treatment  of  equals.  Among  the  areas  of  discrimination  that 
have  come  to  our  attention  are  provincial  and  municipal  tax  concessions  offered 
to  induce  firms  to  select  a  particular  location.  At  the  federal  level,  tax  concessions 
and  subsidies  for  industrial  firms  locating  in  "designated  areas"  of  low  economic 
activity  testify  to  the  belief  that  equal  treatment  must  here  give  way  to  the 
national  interest. 

71.  That  social  policy  may  from  time  to  time  override  the  principles  of  taxa- 
tion is  a  fact  of  life.  And  it  can  be  argued  that  in  a  democratic  setting,  social 
policy  based  on  a  deep-seated  popular  consensus  should  have  priority  over  principles 
in  that  it  represents  the  will  of  the  people.  The  danger  of  this  argument,  however, 
is  that  if  pushed  too  far,  it  sanctions  indiscriminate  trampling  on  the  principles  of 
taxation  and  hence  invites  revenue-raising  by  caprice,  which  is  hardly  compatible 
with  constitutional  democracy.  As  a  Committee  on  Taxation,  we  deem  it  our 
particular  responsibility  to  assess  the  tax  system  in  terms  of  its  conformity  to 
principle,  leaving  to  others  the  interpretation  of  the  dictates  of  social  policy. 

72.  We,  of  course,  recognize  that  social  policy  may  at  times  take  precedence 
over  the  application  of  the  principles  of  taxation.  But  we  believe  that  in  every 
such  instance,  the  case  should  be  clearly  established.  We  confess  that  although 
we  have  bent  every  effort  to  relate  our  recommendations  to  the  principles  that 
we  espouse,  we  have  ourselves  in  the  course  of  this  Report  occasionally  departed 
from  principle  in  deference  to  social  policy — for  example,  with  regard  to  alcohol. 
We  have  taken  scrupulous  care,  however,  to  label  clearly  each  of  our  de- 
partures from  principle  and  to  state  our  reasons  for  them.  But  for  the  vast 
majority  of  the  topics  treated  in  this  Report,  we  do  not  advocate  that  principles 
bow  to  social  policy  in  the  matter  of  provincial  and  municipal  tax  discrimination 
on  the  basis  of  location.  At  this  juncture  we  are  anticipating  the  subject  matter 
of  the  next  chapter. 


22 


Chapter 
2 


The  Cominittee's  Philosophy 
of  Government  Finance: 
Intergovernmental 
Fiscal  Relations 


INTRODUCTION 

1 .  By  our  terms  of  reference,  we  are  required  to  report  upon  the  revenue  system 
not  only  of  the  Province  of  Ontario  but  also  of  its  municipalities,  both  regional  and 
local,  and  of  its  school  boards.  The  philosophy  of  taxation  we  have  set  forth  in 
the  preceding  chapter  is  applicable  to  the  conduct  of  government  at  any  level  within 
our  political  system.  But  given  the  multiplicity  of  these  levels,  we  must  now  unfold 
our  broad  philosophy  of  intergovernmental  fiscal  relationships  with  respect  to  the 
proper  meeting  of  over-all  public  revenue  and  expenditure  responsibilities  within  this 
country.  In  this  latter  connection  it  is  readily  apparent  that  the  Province  of  Ontario 
operates  not  in  a  vacuum  but  as  one  provincial  entity  in  a  greater  Canadian  nation. 
Federal  tax  and  expenditure  policies  vitally  affect  the  economic  development  of 
Ontario,  both  directly  and  indirectly  through  their  impact  on  the  country  as  a 
whole.  Conversely,  Ontario's  economic  policies,  and  those  of  other  provinces,  may 
support  or  impede  both  national  objectives  and  the  objectives  of  sister  provinces. 
We  therefore  find  it  necessary  to  begin  our  discussion  of  the  most  appropriate  fiscal 
relationships  among  the  several  levels  of  government  in  Canada  with  a  statement  of 
our  philosophy  of  federalism  and  of  federal-provincial  fiscal  relations. 


23 


Intergovernmental  Fiscal  Relations 

OUR  PHILOSOPHY  OF  FEDERALISM  AND  ITS  FISCAL 
IMPLICATIONS 

THE  NATURE  OF  FEDERALISM 

2.  Federalism  is  a  system  of  government  that  attempts  to  reconcile  unity  and 
diversity.  More  specifically,  federalism  involves  a  constitutional  division  of 
authority  and  responsibility  between  a  national  government  on  the  one  hand  and 
several  regional  or  provincial  governments  on  the  other.  Under  a  federal  constitu- 
tion, public  functions  are  often  exclusively  allocated  to  one  level  of  government,  as, 
for  example,  defence  to  the  federal  government  and  education  to  the  provinces,  or 
they  may  be  shared,  as,  for  example,  welfare.  Whatever  the  individual  function, 
however,  the  essence  of  federalism  is  that  the  ultimate  executive  and  legislative 
powers  for  the  performance  of  that  function  reside  in  whole  or  in  part  at  one  or  the 
other  level  of  government,  national  or  regional. 

3.  In  Canada  it  is  precisely  this  constitutional  allocation  of  power  between  the 
Dominion  and  the  provinces  that  enables  federalism  to  play  so  well  its  role  in  recon- 
ciling diversity  and  unity.  The  several  provinces  enjoy,  within  the  spheres  of 
activity  assigned  to  them,  constitutionally  guaranteed  authority  to  develop  public 
policies  suited  to  their  peculiar  needs.  At  the  same  time  the  Dominion,  within  its 
own  constitutional  confines,  is  the  repository  of  those  powers  necessary  to  ensure 
the  uniform  discharge  of  functions  that  affect  the  well-being  of  the  country  at 
large. 

OUR  PHILOSOPHY  OF  FEDERALISM 

4.  Our  philosophy  of  federalism  is  based  firmly  on  our  recognition  of  the  value 
of  this  mode  of  government  as  a  constitutional  mechanism  for  the  simultaneous 
promotion  and  mutual  reinforcement  of  unity  and  diversity.  To  be  sure,  the 
pursuit  of  diversity  within  a  framework  of  national  unity,  as  Canadian  history 
attests,  is  neither  easy  nor  automatic.  Healthy  intergovernmental  relations  in  a 
federal  system  can  be  achieved  only  through  continuous  and  unremitting  effort,  on 
the  part  of  all,  to  adjust  to  changing  circumstances. 

5.  We  believe  that  if  any  Canadian  federal  system  is  to  function  satisfactorily, 
its  underlying  fiscal  arrangements  must  reflect  four  basic  principles.  The  first  of 
these  is  autonomy,  which  at  the  provincial  level  requires  that  each  of  the  provinces 
have  the  power  to  determine  its  own  taxation  and  expenditure  programs  and  that  it 
assume  full  political  responsibility  for  its  decisions  in  these  areas.  Provincial 
autonomy  emphasizes  the  fact  of  diversity  among  the  component  parts  of  a  federa- 
tion. 

6.  The  second  principle,  which  we  choose  to  call  economic  mobility,  stresses  a 
federation's  need  for  unity.  Economic  mobility  requires  an  absence  of  internal 
barriers  to  the  geographic  and  occupational  allocation  of  human  and  material 
resources  and  to  the  free  movement  of  goods  and  services.  Any  such  barriers 
lessen  economic  efficiency  and  accordingly  have  no  place  in  a  smoothly  function- 
ing federal  system.    It  follows  that  public  policy  in  a  federal  state  must  be  the 

24 


Chapter  2:   Paragraphs  2-8 

subject  of  close  intergovernmental  co-ordination.  This  should  hold  both  in  the 
economic  realm  and  in  related  fields;  here  steps  recently  initiated  by  Ontario  to 
make  possible  nation-wide  portability  of  pensions  provide  an  excellent  example. 
It  also  follows  that  the  principle  of  provincial  autonomy  provides  no  justification  for 
the  use  of  fiscal  measures  designed  to  distort  the  market  allocation  of  resources  in 
pursuit  of  protectionist  goals.  Interprovincial  differences  in  tax  levels,  in  grants 
and  welfare  payments,  and  in  fiscal  incentives  to  industry  will  necessarily  affect 
resource  allocation  to  some  degree  but  are  potentially  subject  to  co-ordination.  Far 
more  serious  are  provincial  policies  deUberately  restrictive  and  discriminatory  in 
nature,  of  which  preferential  purchasing  policies  and  "buy  provincial"  campaigns 
are  leading  examples.  The  difficult  harmonization  of  national  and  provincial 
economic  interests  will  scarcely  be  promoted  by  the  independent  use  of  restrictive 
poUcies  by  the  provincial  governments,  the  main  effects  of  which  must  be  a  lower- 
ing of  the  productivity  of  the  Canadian  economy  and  the  shifting  of  some  part  of 
the  costs  of  uneconomic  provincial  policies  to  outsiders. 

7.  Our  third  and  fourth  principles  are  designed  to  smooth  the  path  of  reconcilia- 
tion between  diversity  and  unity,  between  provincial  autonomy  and  economic 
mobility.  The  third  principle  is  that  of  equalization,  which  impUes  that  it  is  both 
necessary  and  appropriate  to  ensure  that  every  province  have  the  financial  capacity 
to  provide  pubUc  services  at  a  level  that  is  regarded  as  minimally  satisfactory,  by 
generally  accepted  Canadian  standards.  If  such  minimal  financial  capacity  is  not 
made  available  to  every  provincial  government,  provincial  autonomy  will  be  illusory 
because  certain  provinces  will  lack  the  resources  to  meet  the  costs  of  their  basic 
services.  The  Rowell-Sirois  Commission  noted  twenty-five  years  ago,  a  grossly 
"unequal  distribution  of  the  national  income  as  between  the  people  of  different 
regions  may  excite  feelings  quite  as  dangerous  to  national  unity  as  those  aroused 
by  gross  inequalities  between  different  income  groups".^  For  reasons  which  we 
shall  advance  later,  we  beUeve  that,  as  a  general  proposition,  equalization  should 
apply  directly  to  provincial  revenues  rather  than  to  provincial  expenditure.  We 
recognize,  of  course,  that  there  may  be  the  occasional  case  for  exceptions  to  this 
rule,  particularly  where  the  provision  by  the  provinces  of  a  particular  service  at  a 
nationally  uniform  standard  is  deemed  necessary.  The  Trans-Canada  Highway 
project  is  a  recent  example. 

8.  As  a  fourth  and  final  principle,  we  beUeve  that  co-operation,  both  federal- 
provincial  and  interprovincial,  is  an  essential  ingredient  of  federalism.  Provincial 
autonomy,  clearly  understood,  cannot  operate  in  a  vacuum  when  the  interdepen- 
dence of  the  provinces  within  a  thriving  national  economy  is  a  fact  of  twentieth- 
century  life.  Conversely,  the  federal  goverimient  cannot  hope  to  discharge  its 
responsibilities  effectively  without  taking  into  account  the  impact  of  its  policies  upon 
the  provinces.  If  ever  a  luxury,  co-operation  between  the  federal  government  and 
the  provinces,  and  among  the  provinces,  especially  in  the  formulation  and  imple- 
mentation of  economic  policy,  has  now  become  a  vital  necessity.    The  need  for 

^Royal  Commission  on  Dominion-Provincial  Relations,  Report,  Vol.  11,  Ottawa:  King's 
Printer,  1940,  p.  10. 

25 


Intergovernmental  Fiscal  Relations 

co-operation  extends  from  the  highest  ministerial  level  to  the  more  specialized 
compartments  of  the  pubhc  service,  and  its  scope  ranges  from  the  realm  of  broad 
fiscal  and  economic  issues  to  such  highly  specialized  fields  as  conservation,  public 
health  and  tax  administration. 

9.  We  believe  that  intergovernmental  co-operation  is  vital  to  the  achievement 
of  at  least  five  important  ends.  First  is  simply  the  exchange  of  information.  A 
frequently  cited  advantage  of  federalism  is  that  it  gives  a  nation  the  advantage  of 
many  governments,  each  of  which  is  a  laboratory  for  policy  experiments.  Com- 
munication is  indispensable  if  the  benefits  of  experimentation  are  to  be  reaped 
fully.  Second  is  the  recognition  and  identification  of  common  problems.  Whether 
in  matters  of  health  or  education,  welfare  or  transportation,  governments  should 
have  the  opportunity  to  discover  the  extent  to  which  they  share  similar  challenges. 
Third  is  research.  Joint  efforts  in  the  quest  for  solutions  to  common  problems  are 
often  the  logical  outcome  of  the  identification  of  such  problems.  Fourth  is  the 
elimination  of  needless  and  wasteful  duplication.  The  achievement  of  this  end  is 
entirely  dependent  on  the  smooth  accomplishment  of  the  first  three.  Fifth  is  the 
negotiation  of  common  solutions.  It  is  here  perhaps  more  than  anywhere  else  that 
regional  diversity  and  national  unity  will  be  reconciled  to  the  greatest  effect.  The 
negotiation  of  solutions  to  common  problems,  while  more  frequent  now  than  in  the 
past,  remains  a  relatively  untapped  resource  of  Canadian  federalism.  We  shall 
argue  later  in  this  chapter  that  such  negotiation  provides  the  key  both  to  the  formu- 
lation of  effective  economic  policies  and  to  the  achievement  of  national  standards 
in  many  fields  of  expenditure  responsibility  at  present  covered  by  conditional  grants. 

10.  Our  philosophy  of  federahsm  as  a  mode  of  government  whose  purpose  is 
the  reconciliation  of  diversity  and  unity  has  led  us  to  formulate  four  basic  prin- 
ciples: provincial  autonomy,  economic  mobility,  equalization  and  co-operation.  We 
shall  now  seek  to  apply  these  principles  to  the  division  of  spending  and  revenue 
responsibilities  in  Canada,  to  intergovernmental  grants,  and  to  the  taxation  by  one 
government  of  other  governmental  entities. 

THE  DIVISION  OF  EXPENDITURE  RESPONSIBILITIES 

11.  In  approaching  the  division  of  expenditure  responsibilities  in  Canada,  our 
starting  point,  explicit  in  our  terms  of  reference,  is  the  British  North  America  Act. 
The  federal-provincial  division  of  powers  and  responsibilities  laid  down  in  this 
document  has  in  fact  proved  much  more  flexible  than  certain  contemporary  critics 
of  the  Canadian  constitution  seem  to  believe.  In  making  this  statement,  we  are  not 
thinking  merely  of  formal  amendments  such  as  those  transferring  jurisdiction  over 
unemployment  insurance  and  old  age  pensions  to  the  federal  government.  We  note 
more  especially  the  many  applications  of  the  federal  spending  power  to  grants  in 
such  fields  as  highways,  health  care  and  public  welfare,  grants  which  have  served 
to  blend  federal  and  provincial  jurisdictions  in  the  pursuit  of  goals  nationally  agreed 
upon.  We  are  also  particularly  mindful  of  the  growth,  both  in  importance  and 
numbers,  of  intergovernmental  consultative  bodies.  These  bodies,  the  spectrum  of 
whose  activity  ranges  from  the  virtually  all-inclusive  scope  of  federal-provincial 

26 


Chapter  2:  Paragraphs  9-14 

conferences  at  the  prime-ministerial  level  to  the  very  specific  task  of  the  National 
Potato  Breeding  Committee  at  the  technical  level,-  have  had  the  net  effect  of 
transforming  Canadian  federalism  from  one  of  exclusively  divided  powers  into  a 
federalism  of  shared  responsibility. 

12.  Constitutional  amendments,  applications  of  expenditure  policy,  and  the 
growth  of  intergovernmental  consultative  machinery  have  all  wrought  substantial 
changes  in  the  dimensions  of  Canadian  federalism.  These  changes  are  ample  testi- 
mony to  the  fact  that  the  Canadian  constitution  offers  a  generous  measure  of 
flexibility.  Without  necessarily  approving  each  and  every  change  in  detail,  we 
applaud  the  degree  to  which  the  Canadian  constitution  has  proved  itself  adaptable 
to  the  challenges  of  one  hundred  years  of  history.  Those  who  persist  in  observing 
that  the  British  North  America  Act  is  a  remnant  of  the  horse-and-buggy  age  simply 
ignore  constitutional  developments  which  make  contemporary  Canadian  federalism 
as  different  from  its  1867  version  as  a  jet  plane  is  from  a  stage  coach. 

13.  We  believe  that  no  division  of  powers  between  the  federal  and  provincial 
governments  can  be  rigidly  maintained  for  all  time.  Flexibility  is  the  prime  test  of 
a  sound  constitution.  Just  as  depression,  war  and  economic  growth  have  forced 
some  striking  changes  in  Canadian  federalism  since  1867,  so  will  the  adaptability 
of  the  constitution  to  further  change  continue  to  be  severely  tested  during  its 
second  century.  It  is  within  such  a  framework  of  flexibility  that  we  believe  that 
our  four  principles  of  federalism — provincial  autonomy,  economic  mobility, 
equalization  and  co-operation — can  serve  as  useful  guides  to  the  division  of  govern- 
mental responsibilities  within  a  federal  system. 

14.  Provincial  autonomy,  within  the  jurisdictional  sphere  assigned  to  the  prov- 
inces under  the  constitution,  is  indispensable  to  ensure  that  the  responsibilities  of 
these  governments  wiU  be  clearly  pinpointed  in  the  public  mind.  In  the  words  of 
the  Rowell-Sirois  Commission,  "If  a  province  chooses  to  provide  inferior  services 
and  impose  lower  taxation  it  is  free  to  do  so,  or  it  may  provide  better  services  than 
the  average  if  its  people  are  willing  to  be  taxed  accordingly,  or  it  may,  for  example, 
starve  its  roads  and  improve  its  education,  or  starve  its  education  and  improve  its 
roads. "^  Within  its  jurisdictional  sphere,  in  brief,  a  province  must  be  free  to  deter- 
mine its  own  expenditure  priorities  and  its  own  levels  of  taxation.  Only  in  this  way 
will  a  province  stand  fully  accountable  at  the  bar  of  public  opinion.  Critics  of 
provincial  autonomy  may  well  inquire  if  the  freedom  of  provinces  to  determine 
priorities  and  levels  of  expenditure  is  not  disruptive  to  national  unity.  To  this  we 
reply  that  it  is  necessary  to  bear  in  mind  that  citizens  of  several  provinces  are  also 
citizens  of  Canada.  It  is  unlikely  that  informed  public  opinion  in  any  given  prov- 
ince will  long  tolerate  severe  discrepancies  in  provincial  performance,  and  all  the 
more  so  if  provincial  responsibility  is  clear  and  inescapable. 


^This  little  known  committee  convenes  officials  of  the  federal  Department  of  Agricul- 
ture, together  with  their  provincial  counterparts.  It  is  but  one  example  of  what  are 
literally  dozens  of  specialized  intergovernmental  committees. 

'Royal  Commission  on  Dominion-Provincial  Relations,  Report,  Vol.  II,  p.  84. 

27 


Intergovernmental  Fiscal  Relations 

15.  In  this  connection,  we  wish  to  emphasize  that  those  functions  whose  bene- 
fits are  clearly  indivisible  and  whose  performance  has  a  direct  impact  on  economic 
mobihty  should  remain  unambiguously  federal.  There  can  be  no  question,  for 
example,  that  defence,  whose  benefits  are  hardly  divisible  on  a  regional  basis,  must 
be  a  federal  responsibility.  The  regulation  of  international  and  interprovincial  trade, 
of  the  monetary  and  banking  system,  and  of  unemployment  insurance,  with  their 
obvious  consequences  for  the  free  movement  of  goods,  capital,  and  labour,  are 
likewise  appropriate  subjects  of  exclusive  federal  jurisdiction.  Federal  autonomy 
is  surely  an  indispensable  counterpart  to  provincial  autonomy,  in  that  ample  scope 
for  independent  federal  action  is  necessary,  not  only  to  ensure  national  security  and 
economic  mobility  but  also  to  pinpoint  public  accountability  for  the  proper  discharge 
of  those  functions  that  demand  provision  on  a  nationally  uniform  base.  In  stressing 
the  independence  of  each  of  the  two  constitutionally  estabUshed  levels  of  govern- 
ment in  Canada,  and  the  close  link  between  autonomy  and  responsibility,  we  never- 
theless recognize  that  there  are  many  points  at  which  respective  expenditure  func- 
tions of  the  federal  and  provincial  governments  are  intertwined.  This  is  where 
co-operation  and,  to  a  lesser  extent,  equahzation,  have  an  important  role  to  play. 

THE  DIVISION  OF  REVENUE  POWERS 

16.  Under  the  British  North  America  Act,  the  revenue  powers  of  the  federal 
government  are  said  to  extend  to  "the  raising  of  money  by  any  mode  or  system 
of  taxation".^  Provincial  revenue  powers,  for  their  part,  are  composed  of  "direct 
taxation  within  the  Province  in  order  to  the  raising  of  a  revenue  for  provincial 
purposes";^  "the  management  and  sale  of  public  lands  belonging  to  the  Province 
and  of  the  timber  and  wood  thereon";'*  and  "shop,  saloon,  tavern,  auctioneer,  and 
other  licences  in  order  to  the  raising  of  a  revenue  for  provincial,  local,  or  municipal 
purposes".'^  The  comparatively  limited  revenue  powers  granted  to  the  provinces 
were  consistent  with  the  view  of  the  Fathers  of  Confederation  that,  of  the  two 
levels  of  government,  the  federal  faced  by  far  the  more  onerous  burden  of 
expenditure. 

17.  As  in  the  sphere  of  spending  responsibilities,  however,  the  Canadian  con- 
stitution again  proved  its  adaptability  to  changing  revenue  requirements  with  the 
passage  of  time.  Faced  with  unforeseen  public  demand  for  education,  welfare,  and 
highway  transportation,  the  provinces,  with  a  strong  helping  hand  from  court  inter- 
pretation of  the  British  North  America  Act  by  the  Judicial  Committee  of  the  Privy 
Council,  greatly  increased  the  scope  of  their  revenue  powers.  "Direct  taxation", 
thought  in  1867  to  extend  to  little  more  than  the  taxation  of  property,  gradually 
become  a  fount  of  revenue  powers  covering  most  forms  of  income,  consumption  and 
wealth.  The  motor  vehicle,  for  its  part,  offered  a  spectacular  instance  whereby  the 
service  needs  created  by  technological  change  were  matched  by  corresponding 
sources  of  revenue — the  gasoline  tax  and  automobile  licences.  Then  too,  world 
demand  for  natural  resources,  both  renewable  and  non-renewable,  coupled  with 


^British  North  America  Act,  1867,  Section  91(3). 
"Section  92(2). 
•Section  92(5). 
'Section  92(9). 

28 


Chapter  2:  Paragraphs  15-21 

successive  discoveries  of  unimagined  riches,  shaped  the  management  of  public 
lands  into  an  asset  of  unexpected  magnitude  to  the  treasuries  of  several  provinces. 

18.  Canadian  federalism  has  accommodated  the  changing  needs  of  the  provinces 
not  only  through  flexible  revenue  powers  but  through  the  constant  revision  of  inter- 
governmental financial  arrangements.  Barely  two  years  after  their  adoption,  the 
statutory  federal-provincial  subsidies  provided  by  the  British  North  America  Act 
"in  full  settlement  of  all  future  demands"**  underwent  the  first  of  a  series  of  adjust- 
ments. More  recently,  in  order  to  give  the  Dominion  wider  scope  for  the  financing 
of  World  War  II,  the  provinces  agreed  to  hold  their  income  tax  powers  in  abeyance 
in  return  for  so-called  "tax  rental"  payments.  The  resulting  centralization  of  fiscal 
powers  was  carried  over  into  the  post-war  era,  then  gradually  eased  as  the  provinces 
sought  financial  accommodation  to  meet  sharply  rising  expenditures  which  reflected 
their  very  rapid  economic  growth.  The  concept  of  tax  rentals  was  replaced  by  that 
of  tax  sharing,  and  a  welter  of  grants,  both  conditional  and  unconditional,  accom- 
panied federal-provincial  developments  in  the  field  of  taxation, 

19.  The  history  of  intergovernmental  finance  leads  us  to  the  inescapable 
conclusion  that  the  division  of  revenue  sources  must  be  highly  adaptable.  Accord- 
ingly, we  reject  the  notion,  popular  in  some  circles,  that  an  enduring  and  clear-cut 
allocation  of  taxing  powers  between  federal  and  provincial  governments  is  desirable. 
It  is  no  more  possible  to  devise  permanent  and  mutually  satisfactory  tax  arrange- 
ments in  1967  than  it  was  in  1867.  Periodic  revision  to  take  account  of  changing 
circumstances  is  the  sine  qua  non  of  a  sound  intergovernmental  revenue  structure. 

20.  Just  as  in  the  case  of  a  flexible  division  of  spending  powers,  we  believe  that 
our  principles  of  autonomy,  economic  mobihty,  equalization  and  co-operation  are 
enormously  relevant  to  a  proper  allocation  of  revenue  powers  at  any  given  point  in 
time.  By  applying  the  principle  of  autonomy  to  federal-provincial  finance,  we 
derive  what  we  consider  to  be  two  highly  important  rules.  The  first  is  that  the 
governmental  entity  responsible  for  spending  money  should,  to  the  greatest  extent 
consistent  with  the  principle  of  equalization,  be  the  entity  responsible  for  raising 
that  money.  The  second  is  that  each  of  the  two  levels  of  government,  federal  and 
provincial,  should  have  access  to  a  balanced  revenue  structure  through  the  taxation 
of  income,  consumption  and  wealth. 

21.  Our  first  rule  requires  no  explanation.  It  is  one  of  the  most  basic  principles 
of  parliamentary  democracy  and  a  keystone  of  responsible  government.  As  to  our 
second  rule,  we  beUeve  that  the  scope  of  provincial  responsibility,  covering  as  it 
does  some  of  the  most  important  spending  functions  of  modern-day  government, 
necessitates  a  revenue  structure  broadly  based  on  income,  consumption  and  wealth, 
in  order  that  expenditure  may  be  financed  by  recourse  to  a  balanced  tax  system. 
We  also  consider  that  a  broad  revenue  structure  at  both  the  federal  and  provincial 
levels  is  the  prime  requisite  for  the  constitutional  flexibility  which  we  deem  so 
important.  An  undesirable  degree  of  rigidity  would  surely  be  the  prime  conse- 
quence of  a  division  of  revenue  that  locked  the  provinces  into  the  exclusive  use  of, 
let  us  say,  the  personal  income  tax  to  the  exclusion  of  all  sales  taxes,  or  vice  versa. 

'Section  118. 

29 


Intergovernmental  Fiscal  Relations 

22.  Just  as  an  autonomous  provincial  role  in  determining  expenditure  levels  and 
priorities  will  lead  to  interprovincial  differences  in  the  provision  of  services,  so  also 
will  provincial  discretion  over  a  wide  variety  of  revenue  sources  result  in  inter- 
provincial differences  in  the  degree  of  tax  burdens.  Interprovincial  differences  in 
tax  levels  can  be  expected  to  have  marginal  consequences  for  national  economic 
mobility,  but  we  believe  that  provincial  policies  of  non-discrimination,  together 
with  equalization  and  co-operation,  will  go  far  toward  mitigating  any  otherwise 
harmful  results.  On  the  other  hand,  provincial  tax  concessions  in  favour,  let  us  say, 
of  resident  corporations,  may  artificially  distort  a  market  allocation  of  resources 
on  a  national  basis  quite  as  much  as  expenditure  poHcies  that  give  preferential 
treatment — for  example,  to  the  local  wine  industry  in  Ontario.  We  wish  to  empha- 
size once  again  our  beUef  that  protectionism,  whether  in  taxing  or  spending,  has  no 
place  in  a  well-ordered  federal  system.  We  fully  endorse  the  position  that  the 
Royal  Commission  on  Dominion-Provincial  Relations  expressed  in  1940  as 
follows :  ^ 

It  is  probable  that  there  is  no  single  province  so  situated  as  to  gain  on 
balance  by  the  existence  of  local  protectionism  in  Canada.  In  each  case  the 
desired  objective  is  sought  with  such  immediacy  that  the  longer  view,  taking 
account  of  secondary  results  and  ultimate  consequences,  is  excluded  from  con- 
sideration. .  .  .  The  damage  done  by  local  protectionism  takes  many  forms; 
among  them,  the  artificial  location  of  industries  within  the  national  economy; 
the  wastes  of  uneconomic  competition;  the  financial  burdens  involved  in  sup- 
porting uneconomic  industries;  the  uncertainty  to  business  everywhere  if  markets 
in  other  provinces  are  in  danger  of  being  shut  off  by  protectionist  devices;  the 
emphasis  laid  on  rivalry  and  jealousy  between  the  provinces. 

In  proper  perspective,  provincial  autonomy  in  raising  of  revenue  is  a  hallmark  of 
public  accountability,  not  a  licence  for  the  creation  of  tax  havens. 

23.  In  addition  to  a  wide  jurisdiction  overtaxation,  genuine  provincial  autonomy 
requires  the  use  of  equalization  payments  designed  to  raise  the  tax  yield  of  poor 
provinces  to  a  level  that  will  enable  these  provinces  to  provide  services  that  conform 
to  at  least  a  minimally  acceptable  Canadian  standard.  Indeed,  we  beUeve  that 
equalization  payments  are  a  sine  qua  non  of  provincial  autonomy  which,  to  be 
effectively  operational,  must  mean  that  no  province  lacks  the  wherewithal  to 
meet  its  basic  service  responsibilities. 

24.  Reserving  our  position  on  the  relationship  of  equalization  payments  to 
economic  mobility  for  treatment  in  the  grants  section  of  this  chapter,  we  wish  to 
record  here  our  opinion  that  the  most  appropriate  index  on  which  to  base  equaliza- 
tion is  provincial  revenue.  The  alternative  indexes  most  often  mentioned  are,  of 
course,  personal  income  within  the  provinces  and  provincial  government  expendi- 
ture, both  of  which  we  consider  distinctly  inferior.  We  reject  the  use  of  personal 
income  as  an  index  of  interprovincial  equalization  for  two  reasons.  First,  we  do 
not  regard  equalization  as  a  policy  designed  to  mitigate  interprovincial  differences 


'Royal  Commission  on  Dominion-Provincial  Relations,  Report,  Vol.  II,  p.  64. 

30 


Chapter  2:  Paragraphs  22-28 

in  total  economic  performance,  both  public  and  private.  On  the  contrary,  we 
view  it  solely  as  a  means  to  shore  up  the  ability  of  provincial  governments  to  meet 
minimum  service  standards.  It  follows  that  equalization  should  take  place  primarily 
with  reference  to  the  public  treasury  and  not  to  the  provincial  economy.  Second, 
the  argument  that  the  abihty  of  a  provincial  government  to  provide  services  is 
synonymous  with  an  aggregate  index  of  economic  performance  as  measured  by 
personal  income,  a  measure  that  includes  public  transfer  payments,  is  most  dubious. 
For  instance,  a  province  well  endowed  with  natural  resources  and  able  to  tax  their 
exploitation  may  have  a  government  more  able  by  far  to  provide  acceptable  levels 
of  service  than  a  province  that  is  less  well  endowed  but  has  a  higher  level  of 
personal  income. 

25.  To  reject  provincial  expenditure  as  an  alternative  index  for  equalization 
purposes  may  appear  odd  at  first  blush.  Equalization,  after  all,  looks  toward 
minimally  satisfactory  standards  of  service.  Nevertheless,  we  believe  that  there  exist 
three  strong  arguments  for  bypassing  provincial  spending  as  a  suitable  index,  under 
all  but  exceptional  circumstances.  In  the  first  place,  formulas  that  seek  to  equalize 
on  the  basis  of  provincial  spending  or  on  the  cost  of  provincial  services  are  very 
difficult  to  devise  and,  once  formulated,  tend  to  be  extremely  complex  and  of  but 
temporary  validity.  Moreover,  the  measurement  of  provincial  expenditure  discrep- 
ancies on  specific  services  can  lead  at  best  to  comparisons  that  are  odious  and  that 
might  infringe  on  provincial  autonomy,  and  at  worst  to  comparisons  that  are  invalid 
because  different  provinces  set  different  service  priorities.  Finally,  because  econo- 
mists generally  recognize  that  the  bulk  of  interprovincial  expenditure  discrepancies 
are  due  to  differences  in  fiscal  capacity,  equalizing  with  reference  to  provincial 
spending  is  an  attempt  to  cope  with  what  are  in  large  part  symptoms  rather  than 
causes. 

26.  We  are  thus  left  with  provincial  revenue  as  a  final  possible  index  for  equal- 
izing interprovincial  disparities.  We  wish  to  make  it  plain,  however,  that  our 
preference  for  this  particular  index  stems  from  more  than  a  simple  process  of 
elimination.  It  is  our  considered  opinion  that  the  equalization  of  provincial  differ- 
entials in  selected  tax  yields  has  positive  merits  of  a  high  order.  First,  the  equaliza- 
tion of  tax  yields  applies  to  revenue  deficiencies  that  directly  reflect  underlying 
economic  conditions.  Second,  this  method  works  directly  on  the  most  important 
cause  of  expenditure  deficiency.  Third,  and  of  great  practical  importance,  experi- 
ence has  shown  that  this  same  method  can  be  applied  through  the  use  of  relatively 
simple  formulas. 

27.  As  a  general  proposition,  then,  we  favour  equahzation  on  the  basis  of  inter- 
provincial revenue  discrepancies.  We  believe  that  the  choice  of  taxes  whose  yields 
are  subject  to  equalization  must  be  made  with  care,  as  must  the  selection  of  the 
level  to  which  equalization  will  be  carried.  Reserving  more  specific  comments  on 
these  matters  for  later  discussion,  we  shall  simply  make  four  supplementary  observa- 
tions at  this  point. 

28.  First,  we  are  of  the  opinion  that  the  equahzation  of  provincial  tax  yields 
should  include  the  broad  range  of  taxes  levied  by  provincial  governments  on  income, 

31 


Intergovernmental  Fiscal  Relations 

consumption  and  wealth.  Accordingly,  retail  sales  taxes  have  a  potential  role  in 
equalization  quite  as  great  as  that  now  occupied  by  income  and  inheritance  taxes 
and  natural  resource  revenues. 

29.  Second,  we  think  that  taxes  which  are  justified  in  large  part  on  the  basis 
of  benefits  received  should  not  be  equalized.  The  yield  from  such  taxes  is  itself  the 
index  of  the  demand  for  the  services  to  which  the  tax  is  related.  For  example,  a 
province  whose  yield  from  the  motor  fuel  tax  is  higher  than  that  of  another  also 
has  a  traffic  level  that  demands  higher  road  expenditure.  To  equalize  under  such 
circumstances  would  be  to  provide  funds  where  no  corresponding  need  exists. 

30.  Third,  equalization  of  appropriate  provincial  tax  yields  should  not  be  con- 
ditional on  the  actual  provincial  imposition  of  a  tax  at  any  specified  level  of  rates. 
The  principle  of  autonomy  demands  that  provincial  legislatures  be  responsible  for 
the  level  of  rates  effective  within  their  jurisdiction,  while  the  principle  of  equalization 
requires  intergovernmental  transfers  related  to  standard  rates. 

3 1 .  Fourth,  and  finally,  it  should  almost  go  without  saying  that  no  equalization 
formula — as  for  that  matter  no  division  of  revenue  sources  between  federal  and 
provincial  governments — should  be  envisaged  as  a  permanent  solution  to  the 
dilemmas  of  Canadian  public  finance.  Frequent  intergovernmental  consultation, 
together  with  periodic  revisions,  provides  the  only  realistic  foundation  for  sound 
equalization  policies. 

JOINT  OCCUPANCY  OF  TAX  FIELDS 

32.  In  matters  affecting  provincial  revenue,  equalization  is,  of  course,  but  a 
single  facet  of  the  need  for  extensive  co-operation.  Co-operation  in  all  matters  is 
of  necessity  the  handmaiden  of  federal  and  provincial  autonomy.  Let  us  now  pursue 
this  theme  with  respect  to  a  critically  important  problem  area,  that  of  the  so-called 
"joint  occupancy"  of  tax  fields.  To  say  as  we  do  that  provincial  governments  should 
have  a  revenue  structure  broadly  based  on  the  taxation  of  income,  consumption 
and  wealth  is  to  say  that  provincial  governments  will  occupy  these  fields  of  taxation 
jointly  with  the  federal  government.  We  fully  recognize  that  joint  occupancy  poses 
a  stiff  challenge  to  the  principles  of  certainty,  simplicity,  convenience,  and  economy 
of  collection  and  compliance,  principles  which,  as  developed  in  the  preceding 
chapter,  we  espouse  as  foundation  stones  of  a  sound  revenue  system.  This  challenge 
can  only  be  met  through  intergovernmental  co-operation. 

33.  Three  forms  of  intergovernmental  co-operation  are  necessary  if  the  joint 
occupancy  of  tax  fields  is  to  proceed  on  an  orderly  basis.  The  first  involves  common 
standards  of  legislation  in  jointly  occupied  fields  of  taxation.  The  second  concerns 
federal-provincial  tax  collection  agencies.  And  the  third  involves  interprovincial 
tax  agreements.    Let  us  consider  these  in  turn. 

34.  The  existence  of  autonomous  provinces,  differing  in  political  complexion, 
social  needs  and  service  priorities,  precludes  uniform  rates  of  taxation  in  the 
revenue  fields  that  they  occupy  jointly.  Autonomy,  however,  does  not  preclude 
federal  and  provincial  legislation  so  framed  that  the  bases  of  taxes  jointly  ex- 
ploited will  be  uniform  throughout  Canada.    We  wish  to  stress  that  the  practical 

32 


Chapter  2:  Paragraphs  29-37 

advantages  of  such  legislation  are  enormous.  For  the  taxpayer  doing  business  in 
more  than  one  province,  a  uniform  tax  base  greatly  reduces  the  cost  of  compliance, 
both  in  monetary  and  psychic  terms.  For  the  governments  involved,  a  uniform 
tax  base  substantially  eases  the  task  of  enforcement,  with  corresponding  savings  in 
administrative  costs  and  increments  in  revenue.  Uniformity  of  base  is  particularly 
critical  in  the  major  tax  fields  affecting  income,  consumption  and  wealth,  all  of  which 
are  derived  in  large  part  from  economic  activity  that  is  carried  out  on  a  national 
scale. 

35.  A  practical  example  of  the  extent  to  which  the  Government  of  Ontario  is 
already  concerned  with  intergovernmental  co-operation  in  tax  matters  can  be  found 
in  our  terms  of  reference,  which  direct  us  "to  co-operate  with  the  Royal  Commission 
on  Taxation  and  with  any  other  bodies  of  inquiry  appointed  by  other  provincial 
governments".  Pursuant  to  this  directive  we  have  participated  in  inter-commission 
meetings  which  yielded  much  common  ground  for  complementary  tax  legislation, 
evidence  of  which  is  scattered  throughout  our  recommendations.  Our  experience 
has  impressed  us  with  both  the  need  for  continuing  efforts  in  promoting  uniform 
bases  of  taxation  and  the  practicability  of  such  ettorts. 

36.  Where  a  major  tax,  such  as  one  on  personal  or  corporate  income,  is  every- 
where levied  by  federal  and  provincial  governments  alike,  both  a  uniform  base  and 
a  single  collection  agency  are  to  be  strongly  recommended.  In  the  case  of  the  per- 
sonal income  tax,  we  place  a  major  premium  on  the  convenience  to  employers  in 
withholding,  and  to  individuals  in  filing,  according  to  the  directives  and  standards 
of  a  single  tax  collection  agency.  We  accordingly  approve  of  the  present  federal- 
provincial  tax  arrangements  whereby  Ontario  has  been  able  to  enter  into  a  collec- 
tion agreement  with  the  federal  government,  in  return  for  imposing  taxes  on  an 
income  base  identical  to  that  of  the  federal.  As  for  the  corporation  income  tax,  we 
are  impressed,  as  are  all  students  of  this  tax,  with  the  inherent  complexity  of  allo- 
cating profits  from  nation-wide  business  activity  on  a  provincial  basis.  Provincial 
occupancy  of  this  tax  field  is  a  de  facto  infringement  on  the  principles  of  simplicity 
and  convenience.  We  recognize,  of  course,  the  practical  necessity  for  such  occu- 
pancy; hence  we  are  all  the  more  concerned  that  provincial  exploitation  of  this  tax 
be  based  on  uniform  legislation  and  a  single  collection  agency. 

37.  There  are  two  thoroughly  valid  arguments  against  particular  features  of  the 
present  federal-provincial  tax  collection  arrangements.  The  first  disadvantage  is 
that  a  province,  in  agreeing  to  adhere  to  the  federal  tax  base  for  purposes  of 
uniformity,  has  virtually  no  practical  recourse  against  the  erosion  of  its  revenue 
base,  whether  sudden  or  gradual,  through  unilateral  changes  in  federal  tax  laws.  The 
protection  of  provincial  revenues  requires  that  any  changes  in  the  base  of  the 
personal  income  tax  or  any  other  tax  where  a  collection  agreement  exists,  reflect 
joint  agreement  rather  than  unilateral  decision.  The  second  disadvantage  is  that 
a  province's  right  to  conduct  separate  audits  may  be  unduly  circumscribed.  These 
twin  disadvantages,  while  not  deemed  by  Ontario  to  be  sufficiently  great  to  forestall 
a  collection  agreement  with  respect  to  the  personal  income  tax,  are  at  least  partially 
responsible  for  the  lack  of  an  accord  on  corporation  income  tax. 

33 


Intergovernmental  Fiscal  Relations 

38.  We  therefore  propose  that  full  federal-provincial  consultation  on  tax  legis- 
lation should  take  place  on  an  annual  basis  and  that  all  future  tax  collection  arrange- 
ments should  give  to  provinces  equal  audit  rights  with  the  federal  government. 
These  co-operative  steps  provide  the  key  to  reconciling  the  integrity  of  the  tax  base 
in  jointly  occupied  tax  fields  with  the  principles  of  simphcity  and  convenience.  Such 
steps  do  not  challenge  federal  or  provincial  autonomy  so  long  as  mutually  exclusive 
jurisdiction  over  tax  rates  is  retained. 

39.  Our  strong  inclination  towards  enhanced  co-operation  in  the  domain  of 
tax  fields  jointly  occupied  by  the  federal  and  provincial  levels  extends  to  the  purely 
interprovincial  realm  as  well.  In  concrete  terms,  we  are  particularly  concerned  with 
the  present  condition  of  retail  sales  taxation  in  Canada.  There  exists  appreciable 
tax  avoidance  on  transactions  involving  purchases  of  goods  in  one  province  for 
consumption  in  another.  We  accordingly  favour  interprovincial  collection  agree- 
ments, agreements  whose  implementation  can  be  facilitated  through  interprovin- 
cially  uniform  schedules  of  taxable  items.  Our  own  consultation  with  other  pro- 
vincial tax  commissions  has  impressed  us  with  the  feasibility  of  such  a  step.  We  also 
note,  purely  as  a  matter  of  principle,  that  there  is  no  reason  why  interprovincial 
agreements  for  sales  tax  collection  could  not  be  expanded  to  accommodate  the 
conversion  of  the  federal  manufacturers'  sales  tax  to  a  tax  at  the  retail  field. 

40.  It  is  evident  that  we  place  a  high  premium  on  intergovernmental  co-opera- 
tion in  the  raising  of  revenue.  Both  the  administrative  rationality  of  the  tax  system 
and  its  proper  application  to  social  ends  depend  entirely  upon  a  network  of  frank, 
constant  and  effective  federal-provincial  and  interprovincial  consultation. 

THE  ROLE  OF  GRANTS 

41.  Our  treatment  of  the  division  of  expenditure  and  revenue  responsibilities 
under  federalism  has  already  touched  upon  the  place  of  grants  in  an  intergovern- 
mental fiscal  system.  We  wish  at  this  point  to  focus  yet  closer  attention  upon  the 
role  of  federal-provincial  transfer  payments  in  Canadian  public  finance. 

42.  The  making  of  grants  in  one  form  or  another  is  as  old  as  Canada  itself. 
What  are  the  reasons  for  such  transactions?  Viewed  from  the  broadest  possible 
perspective,  grants  exist  because  no  division  of  tax  powers  and  spending  functions 
can  be  devised  to  meet  precisely  all  the  fiscal  demands  that  federalism  is  called  upon 
to  meet.  More  specifically,  grants  come  about  for  three  reasons: 

(1)  to  make  up  across-the-board  deficiencies  in  provincial  revenue  (revenue 
deficiency  grants). 

(2)  to  even  out  gross  interprovincial  disparities  in  fiscal  capacity  (equaliza- 
tion grants); 

(3)  to  encourage  provinces  to  launch  or  maintain  certain  services  on  a 
nationally  uniform  scale  (stimulation  grants). 

Grants  made  in  pursuit  of  the  first  objective  are  nearly  always  unconditional  in 
nature,  i.e.,  they  provide  funds  which  can  be  spent  as  a  province  sees  fit.  Those 
paid  for  the  second  reason  can  be  either  unconditional  or  conditional.  If  the  latter, 

34 


Chapter  2:  Paragraphs  38-46 

they  are  tied  to  a  designated  proportion  of  provincial  spending  on  a  specific 
function.  The  third  kind  of  grant  is  always  conditional.  Let  us  briefly  review  these 
various  grants  in  turn. 

Revenue  Deficiency  Grants 

43.  Such  grants  occupy  a  time-honoured  place  in  Canadian  federalism.  The 
original  Confederation  subsidies  were  brought  into  being  because  the  estimated 
yield  of  the  revenue  sources  granted  to  the  provinces  under  the  British  North 
America  Act  of  1867  fell  somewhat  short  of  anticipated  provincial  expenditure. 
Much  later,  during  World  War  II,  all  provinces  received  revenue  deficiency  grants 
in  exchange  for  holding  their  income  tax  powers  in  abeyance,  and  in  recognition 
of  the  fiscal  effects  of  federally  imposed  rationing  of  gasoline  and  liquor.  Subse- 
quently, under  a  series  of  post-war  arrangements  lasting  until  1962,  all  provinces 
except  Quebec  and — save  for  the  five  years  from  1952  to  1957 — Ontario,  received 
large  federal  payments  in  return  for  "renting"  their  revenue  powers  over  personal 
income,  corporation  income,  and  successions. 

44.  As  a  general  proposition,  we  are  strongly  opposed  to  revenue  deficiency 
grants.  Such  grants  constitute  a  singular  violation  of  the  principle  of  governmental 
autonomy,  which  links  the  freedom  of  each  level  of  government  to  determine  its 
expenditures  program  with  its  responsibility  for  legislating  its  own  taxes.  We 
recognize  that  revenue  deficiency  grants  can  occasionally  be  necessary  to  give 
federalism  the  flexibility  necessary  to  tide  it  over  such  major  emergencies  as  a  war 
or  a  prolonged  depression.  But  over  the  long  run,  such  grants  have  no  place  as  a 
major  revenue  channel  in  a  well-ordered  federated  fiscal  system.  The  preferred 
alternative  to  deficiency  grants  is  to  be  found  in  an  appropriate  division  of  revenue 
powers  supplemented  by  equalization  payments  where  necessary. 

Equalization  Grants 

45.  We  have  already  indicated  that  transfer  payments  designed  to  enable 
fiscally  poor  provinces  to  provide  levels  of  service  that  are  minimally  acceptable  by 
average  Canadian  standards  are  an  indispensable  adjunct  of  provincial  autonomy 
and  national  unity.  We  have  also  taken  pains  to  state  why  it  is  our  opinion  that 
such  payments  should  be  based  on  deficiencies  in  provincial  tax  yields  rather  than 
on  levels  of  personal  income  or  provincial  expenditure  and  that  benefits-related  taxes 
should  be  excluded  from  any  equalization  formula.  Recapitulating  our  position  in  a 
single  sentence,  we  believe  that  equalization  on  the  basis  of  non-benefits  tax  yields  is 
simpler,  more  accurate,  and  more  in  keeping  with  provincial  autonomy  than  equali- 
zation through  other  methods.  Again  with  regard  to  provincial  autonomy,  equaliza- 
tion payments  should  be  unconditional. 

46.  To  be  sure,  we  offer  the  above  beliefs  in  the  form  of  a  general  rule  rather 
than  an  all-pervading  dogma.  We  recognize  the  possibility  that  equalization  on  the 
basis  of  a  tax-yield  formula  may  not  in  practice  meet  the  basic  needs  of  the  very 
poorest  provinces.  This  is  indeed  true  at  present  with  regard  to  the  Atlantic  region. 
Under  these  circumstances,  supplementary  unconditional  payments  on  a  basis  other 
than  tax  yield  have  a  place  in  federal-provincial  finance.    We  recognize  also  that 

35 


Intergovernmental  Fiscal  Relations 

grants  of  a  conditional  type  can  create  serious  inequities  for  fiscally  weak  provinces. 
Here  too,  subject  to  important  qualifications  to  be  discussed  below,  a  measure  of 
equalization  may  be  appropriate.  But  before  tackling  this  specific  problem,  we 
wish  to  expound  our  general  position  on  the  extent  to  which  equalization  measures 
of  any  kind  are  appropriate. 

47.  To  be  properly  grounded,  equalization  policy  involves  two  difficult  judg- 
ments, one  on  the  basis  of  ethics,  the  other  on  the  basis  of  economics.  The  ethical 
judgment  invokes  an  application  of  the  basic  rule  of  equity  which  states  that  indi- 
viduals similarly  situated  should  be  treated  similarly.  The  economic  judgment,  for 
its  part,  attempts  to  gauge  the  role  of  equalization  in  promoting  or  distorting  an 
optimum  allocation  of  the  country's  resources. 

48.  In  approving  equalization  from  the  standpoint  of  equity,  certain  authorities 
have  taken  the  view  that  individuals  similarly  situated  as  to  income  should  receive 
equal  fiscal  treatment,  wherever  they  may  reside,  taking  into  account  both  their 
tax  burdens  and  their  benefits  from  public  services.^"  This  approach  in  effect 
eliminates  the  influence  of  geography  as  a  factor  contributing  to  the  unequal  fiscal 
treatment  of  Canadian  residents.  We  reject  this  doctrine  of  geographical  neutrality 
as  unsound  in  principle  and  impossible  in  practice.  In  our  own  view,  geographic 
location  cannot  itself  be  ignored  in  determining  whether  or  not  individuals  are  in 
fact  similarly  treated  in  a  federal  nation.  The  very  notion  of  federalism  as  a  form 
of  government  incorporating  and  facilitating  regional  diversity  means  that  geogra- 
phy is  a  positive  rather  than  a  neutral  factor  in  determining  an  individual's  over-all 
economic  situation.  We  regard  equalization  designed  to  eliminate  fiscal  disparities 
arising  from  geographical  location  as  a  policy  based  on  exaggerated  notions  of 
equity.  It  is  one  thing  to  say  that  gross  disparities  in  the  fiscal  position  of  individuals 
similarly  situated  as  to  income  but  dissimilarly  located  as  to  geography  should  not 
be  tolerated,  and  this  is  a  viewpoint  which  we  support.  It  is  quite  another  thing 
to  say  that  any  and  all  fiscal  disparities  among  such  individuals  should  be  eliminated 
without  regard  to  their  location. 

49.  The  economic  effects  of  equalization,  in  terms  of  its  impact  on  the  optimum 
allocation  of  society's  productive  resources,  is  a  subject  that  has  generated  signifi- 
cant differences  of  opinion  among  students  of  public  finance.  It  is  contended  on  the 
one  hand  that,  in  the  absence  of  equalization,  disparities  in  tax  burdens  and  levels 
of  public  services  will  distort  the  flow  of  labour  and  capital  away  from  the  allegedly 
optimum  pattern  that  would  result  if,  as  defined  above,  government  fiscal  operations 
were  geographically  neutral. ^^  Yet  from  another  perspective,  equalization  payments 
directly  impede  an  optimum  allocation  of  resources  because  they  permit  higher 
levels  of  services  in  poor  provinces  than  would  otherwise  obtain,  thereby  discourag- 
ing the  outward  movement  of  labour  and  capital  to  areas  where  their  marginal 


"See,  for  example,  James  M.  Buchanan,  "Federalism  and  Fiscal  Equity",  American 
Economic  Review,  Vol.  XL,  September  1950;  see  also  John  F.  Graham,  "Fiscal 
Adjustment  in  a  Federal  Country",  Intergovernmental  Fiscal  Relationships,  Toronto: 
Canadian  Tax  Foundation,  1964. 

'Buchanan,  "Federalism  and  Fiscal  Equity";  Graham,  "Fiscal  Adjustment". 

36 


Chapter  2:  Paragraphs  47-51 

productivity  would  be  higher.  ^^  In  a  similar  vein,  it  could  also  be  said  that  equaliza- 
tion payments  have  a  distorting  effect  because  they  lower  the  service  standards 
which  the  more  wealthy  provinces  would  otherwise  be  able  to  provide  and  thereby 
reduce  the  marginal  productivity  of  labour  and  capital  in  these  areas. 

50.  Our  collective  viewpoint  on  equalization  tries  to  take  account  of  both  its 
virtues  and  its  dangers.  On  the  one  hand,  we  recognize  that  equalization  payments 
have  an  important  role  in  evening  out  interprovincial  fiscal  differences  whose  exis- 
tence would  constitute  a  threat  to  optimal  resource  allocation.  Patently  sub- 
standard services  in  the  poor  provinces  can  hinder  labour  mobility  and  discourage 
the  investment  of  otherwise  productive  capital.  On  the  other  hand,  we  are  acutely 
aware  that  equalization  involves  economic  costs  as  well  as  benefits.  Equalization 
payments,  in  detracting  from  the  abihty  of  a  rich  province  to  provide  additional 
services  without  increased  tax  burdens,  adversely  affect  productivity  and  growth  not 
only  regionally  but  nationally. 

51.  In  tending  to  the  view  that  equalization,  if  pursued  too  far,  involves  signifi- 
cant economic  costs  to  the  nation,  we  wish  none  the  less  to  emphasize  that  we 
regard  its  use  as  indispensable  in  the  federal  state  if  equity  is  to  be  achieved. 
In  deciding  the  precise  lengths  to  which  equalization  "should"  be  carried,  an 
extemely  delicate  value  judgment  must  be  made,  one  that  must  balance  the  ends 
of  national  economic  efficiency  and  interprovincial  equity.  At  the  risk  of  sounding 
trite,  we  believe  that  the  only  reasonable  approach  to  equalization  is  one  of  modera- 
tion. Neither  equity  nor  economics  dictates  an  equalization  policy  so  extreme  that 
it  would  seek  to  place  all  parts  of  Canada  on  the  same  fiscal  footing.  At  the  same 
time,  both  considerations  demand  some  measure  of  fiscal  redistribution  among 
provincial  governments.  The  resulting  dilemma  can  perhaps  be  crystallized  to 
some  degree  with  reference  to  current  equalization  practice  which  calls  for  transfer 
payments  sufficient  to  bring  the  per-capita  yield  of  income  and  inheritance  taxes  in 
every  province  to  the  average  per-capita  yield  in  the  two  richest  provinces,  Ontario 
and  British  Columbia.  On  the  one  hand,  there  appears  to  be  no  valid  reason  why 
the  equalization  base  should  not  be  broadened  to  include  consumption  taxes;  sales 
tax  yields  are  surely  as  relevant  an  index  of  provincial  revenue  capacity  as  income 
and  inheritance  levies.  On  the  other  hand,  the  fact  that  equalization  is  now  carried 
to  the  tax  yield  levels  that  obtain  in  Ontario  and  British  Columbia  poses  a  serious 
problem.  Adverse  effects  of  the  present  formula  on  resource  allocation  are  held  in 
check  only  because  a  Umited  number  of  taxes  are  included  within  the  formula.  But 
to  equalize  to  the  level  of  the  two  richest  provinces  on  the  basis  of  all  major  taxes 
would  surely  involve  such  unfortunate  consequences  for  national  economic  growth 
as  to  be  difficult  to  justify  even  in  terms  of  equity.  We  favour  the  inclusion  of  a 
broader  group  of  taxes  in  the  equalization  formula  but  believe  that  the  only  sound 
working  principle  is  to  look  to  average  standards  of  fiscal  performance  as  the 
measure  of  provincial  need.  It  is  in  this  context  that  equalization  grants  have  their 
most  appropriate  role  in  our  fiscal  system. 

^°See,  for  example,  A.  D.  Scott,  "A  Note  on  Grants  in  Federal  Countries",  Economica, 
Vol.  XVII,  November  1950. 

37 


Intergovernmental  Fiscal  Relations 
Stimulation  Grants 

52.  The  rapid  growth  of  so-called  conditional  grants  or  shared  cost  programs 
has  been  a  hallmark  of  post-war  Canadian  federalism.  We  have  chosen  to  group 
these  programs  under  the  heading  "stimulation  grants"  in  the  belief  that  this  designa- 
tion offers  the  most  accurate  description.  Such  grants,  indeed,  are  designed  to 
stimulate  provincial  spending  on  certain  functions,  often  in  accordance  with  pre- 
scribed standards.  With  the  significant  exception  of  the  hospital  insurance  program, 
the  federal  contribution  under  these  grants  is  normally  a  set  percentage  of  total 
program  costs. 

53.  The  standards  which  stimulation  grants  seek  to  promote  on  a  national 
scale  fall  into  three  kinds,  depending  on  the  program.  The  first  and  vaguest  standard 
simply  seeks  to  promote  the  provision  of  a  service.  Thus,  under  the  unemployment 
assistance  program,  all  provinces  are  encouraged  to  provide  relief  to  the  largest  class 
of  indigent  persons — unemployed  individuals  whose  insurance  benefits  are  exhausted 
or  whose  occupations  are  not  covered  under  the  federal  unemployment  insurance 
scheme.  Here  the  federal  contribution  is  simply  based  on  whatever  actual  costs  a 
province  incurs  in  providing  relief  according  to  provincially  determined  scales  of 
assistance.  The  second  type  of  standard  seeks  to  ensure  uniform  coverage  and 
nation-wide  portability  of  service  benefits  without  actually  prescribing  identical 
levels  of  performance  in  every  province.  Such  a  standard  is  peculiar  to  the  provin- 
cial health  insurance  plans  launched  in  accordance  with  the  federal  Hospital  Insur- 
ance and  Diagnostic  Services  Act  of  1957.  Here  federal  payments  are  conditional 
on  interprovincially  uniform  standards  of  coverage  and  provision  of  hospitalization 
for  persons  who  are  taken  ill  outside  their  own  province.  But  the  program  by  no 
means  looks  toward  identical  levels  of  health  care.  The  third  type  of  standard 
involves  the  provision  of  a  service  on  the  basis  of  complete  uniformity.  For 
example,  the  federal-provincial  Trans-Canada  Highway  has  been  built  according 
to  common  engineering  standards.  Just  as  stimulation  grants  seek  to  promote  these 
variously  defined  standards,  so  also  do  they  vary  in  terms  of  their  life  span.  Such 
shared  cost  programs  as  the  Trans-Canada  Highway  are  plainly  of  a  temporary 
nature.  Others,  such  as  health  insurance  and  unemployment  assistance,  give  the 
appearance  of  being  more  or  less  permanent. 

54.  Shared  cost  programs  have  in  recent  years  come  under  increasingly  wide- 
spread criticism,  criticism  with  which  we  have  considerable  sympathy.  We  note 
first  that  these  programs  do  impinge  on  the  capacity  of  a  province  to  determine 
autonomously  its  spending  priorities  and  service  levels.  These  same  programs 
doubtless  exhibit  a  similar  tendency  at  the  federal  level.  It  is  quite  apparent  that 
conditional  grants  can  off"er  a  potential  haven  to  program  officers  and  special 
interests  eager  to  insulate  a  special  function  from  the  review  of  treasury  personnel 
and  elected  officials  at  each  of  the  two  levels  of  government.  We  note  secondly  that 
some  stimulation  grants  may  promote  unrealistic  standards.  Finally,  we  are  im- 
pressed by  the  disproportionate  sacrifices  which  certain  shared  cost  programs  can 
require  different  provinces  to  make.  While  we  join  the  critics  of  shared  cost  pro- 
grams  in  the  above  views,  we   remain  mindful  of  the  benefits   which   national 

38 


Chapter  2:  Paragraphs  52-58 

standards  can  confer  in  the  domain  of  certain  government  activities.  The  question 
of  the  appropriate  place  of  stimulation  grants,  then,  partakes  of  the  essential 
dilemma  of  federalism  itself.  Once  again  the  key  problem  is  to  promote  diversity 
within  a  framework  of  effective  unity. 

55.  We  believe  that  all  existing  shared  cost  programs  should  be  subjected  to 
careful  review.  It  is  our  contention  that  present  programs  have  been  allowed  to 
accumulate  in  number  and  importance  without  adequate  regard  to  the  basic  prin- 
ciples of  autonomy,  economic  mobility,  equalization  and  co-operation.  We  propose 
as  a  basic  starting  proposition  that  governmental  autonomy  should  not  be  infringed 
upon  unless  there  exist  clearly  valid  reasons  for  doing  so.  Such  reasons  will  only  be 
found  in  the  need  to  promote  an  optimal  allocation  of  people,  goods  and  capital 
on  a  national  scale.  The  test  for  the  validity  of  such  reasons  is  not  to  be  found 
through  federal  approbation  alone  but  rather  through  intergovernmental  consulta- 
tion. This  consultation  should  take  place  not  merely  among  officials  interested  in 
a  specific  field  of  activity  but  also  among  those  who  are  charged  with  the  higher 
responsibility  of  determining  broad  service  priorities.  If  a  shared  cost  program 
survives  these  hurdles,  then  consideration  should  be  given  to  grant  formulas  that 
will  equalize  in  some  measure  the  sacrifice  demanded  of  the  provinces  concerned. 
This  we  consider  an  important  exception  to  our  general  rule  that  equalization 
should  not  apply  to  provincial  expenditure. 

56.  We  are  of  the  opinion  that  well-directed  efforts  along  the  above  lines  would 
result  in  a  substantial  rationalization  of  present  stimulation  grants.  Some  would 
fall  by  the  wayside  because  they  simultaneously  induce  budgetary  distortion  and 
promote  unrealistic  standards.  Others,  at  present  envisaged  as  quasi-permanent, 
would  revert  to  a  temporary  status  the  primary  criterion  for  whose  time  span  would 
be  the  period  necessary  to  establish  uniform  coverage  and  nation-wide  portability. 
In  all  instances,  the  potential  of  co-operation  as  a  means  of  obtaining  reasonable 
national  standards  in  the  absence  of  federal  financial  strings  would  be  fully  explored. 
Surviving  and  future  shared  cost  programs  would  be  more  closely  tailored  to  inter- 
governmental consensus  and  financed  on  the  basis  of  equitable  formulas. 

57.  We  do  not  wish  to  conclude  our  discussion  of  shared  cost  programs  without 
reference  to  "contracting  out".  Under  this  recently  established  statutory  arrange- 
ment, a  province  can  decide  to  opt  out  of  certain  specified  conditional  grant  pro- 
grams and  receive  in  lieu  specified  additional  percentages  of  federal  abatement  on 
the  personal  income  tax.  It  is  evident  that  contracting  out  has  the  advantage  of 
allowing  a  shared  cost  program  to  operate  in  the  absence  of  general  federal- 
provincial  consensus  while,  at  the  same  time,  avoiding  the  imposition  of  a  financial 
penalty  on  a  non-agreeing  province.  On  the  other  hand,  it  is  equally  plain  that 
indiscriminate  provision  for  contracting  out  could  jeopardize  the  future  of  all 
national  standards. 

58.  We  believe  that  contracting  out  on  a  limited  scale  may  perhaps  make  a 
long-run  contribution  to  the  flexibility  of  the  Canadian  federal  system.  Such  a 
procedure  could  be  advantageously  invoked  either  when   a  province   is  already 

39 


Intergovernmental  Fiscal  Relations 

providing  a  service  envisaged  under  a  shared  cost  program  or  when  one  or  two 
provinces  are  so  adamantly  opposed  to  an  otherwise  general  agreement  in  favour 
of  a  stimulation  grant  as  to  threaten  the  fibre  of  national  unity.  But  contracting  out 
is  no  substitute  for  a  searching  review  of  shared  cost  programs.  Indeed,  the 
precipitous  introduction  of  this  arrangement  may  well  be  testimony  to  the  possi- 
bility that  such  a  review  has  been  too  long  postponed.  Surely  a  thoroughly 
rationalized  scheme  of  stimulation  grants  can  be  reasonably  expected  to  reduce 
to  a  minimum  the  need  for  contracting  out. 

59.  Grants  have  a  critically  important  role  in  the  domain  of  federal-provincial 
fiscal  relations.  So  convinced  are  we  of  their  importance  that  we  believe  that  all 
grants  must  receive  far  more  searching  scrutiny  than  in  the  past.  Grants  are  not 
a  substitute  for  an  appropriate  and  flexible  division  of  revenue  sources  and  spending 
responsibilities.  But  they  are  the  key  to  appropriate  equalization  measures  and, 
when  grounded  on  federal-provincial  consensus,  can  be  an  indispensable  tool  in  the 
promotion  of  national  unity. 

THE  TAXATION  OF  GOVERP^MENT  ENTITIES 

60.  To  conclude  this  broad  discussion  of  federalism  with  a  note  on  the  position 
of  each  of  the  two  levels  of  government  with  regard  to  the  other's  taxes  may  appear 
at  first  blush  to  constitute  an  all  too  precipitous  descent  from  the  realm  of  generality. 
It  is  because  we  feel  that  important  principles  are  involved  that  we  choose  to 
consider  briefly  this  situation  here. 

61.  The  British  North  America  Act  asserts  clearly  that  "No  lands  or  property 
belonging  to  Canada  or  any  Province  shall  be  liable  to  taxation. "^^  This  assertion 
has  been  construed  to  prohibit  either  the  federal  government  or  a  province  from 
taxing  the  other's  land  or  property.  It  equally  prohibits  a  province  from  taxing 
another  province's  land  or  property  situate  within  its  boundaries.  Furthermore, 
competent  authorities  believe  that  the  prohibition  of  taxation  on  government  land 
and  property  extends  to  all  government  assets  and  transactions,  because  the  Crown 
is  traditionally  immune  from  taxation,  whether  in  right  of  the  Dominion  or  in  right 
of  a  province. 

62.  In  the  nineteenth-century  environment,  governmental  immunity  from  taxa- 
tion posed  no  problems.  The  scope  and  range  of  government  activity  was  limited. 
The  creation  of  public  bodies  to  carry  out  what  are  essentially  business  transactions 
still  lay  in  the  future.  Needless  to  say,  the  advent  of  government  as  a  major 
employer  and  purchaser,  together  with  the  development  of  federal  and  provincial 
Crown  corporations,  has  forced  consideration  of  tax  immunity  in  a  new  light.  When 
governments  begin  to  engage  in  business  activity,  they  enter  into  competition,  direct 
or  indirect,  with  private  business  firms.  In  this  light,  tax  immunity  can  take  on  the 
guise  of  an  unfair  competitive  advantage  in  favour  of  government  enterprise.  More- 
over government,  whether  it  carries  on  business  activity  or  not,  has  grown  to  a  size 
where  its  demands  for  public  services  create  substantial  problems  if  met  on  a 
tax-free  basis. 


'British  North  America  Act,  1867,  Section  125. 

40 


Chapter  2:  Paragraphs  59-66 

63.  The  assumption  of  tax  responsibilities  by  federal  and  provincial  Crown 
corporations  has  now  become  widespread.  Thus  in  the  domain  of  sales  taxation, 
the  federal  manufacturers'  sales  tax  applies  to  purchases  made  by  provincial  Crown 
entities  and  provincial  retail  sales  taxes  likewise  apply  to  federal  corporations.  As 
for  property  taxation — which,  although  municipally  levied,  is  in  constitutional  terms 
a  provincial  tax — the  federal  government  has  in  recent  years  directed  its  Crown 
corporations  to  commence  the  payment  of  full  grants  in  lieu  of  taxes  and  substantial 
progress  has  been  made  in  this  direction.  We  strongly  endorse  as  an  important 
principle  the  assumption  of  full  tax  obligations  by  all  government  business  enter- 
prises in  order  that  they  may  be  on  an  identical  plane  with  private  firms. 

64.  Three  important  considerations  have  led  us  to  the  view  that  full  tax 
liability  should  be  extended  from  Crown  corporations  to  cover  all  departments  of 
government  as  well.  The  first  of  these  is  that  not  all  government  activity  of  a  busi- 
ness enterprise  nature  is  carried  out  under  the  guise  of  public  corporations.  To 
exempt  some  of  this  activity  from  taxation  is  accordingly  to  grant  an  exemption  on 
the  basis  of  an  artificial  and  tenuous  distinction  which  leaves  the  scope  of  the 
exemption  up  to  a  government's  own  discretion  as  to  the  type  of  organization  which 
it  will  select  to  discharge  its  functions.  The  second  is  that  exemptions  of  any  kind 
impinge  upon  the  simplicity  of  a  tax  system  and  involve  ipso  facto  erosion  of  a  tax 
base.  Our  view  of  any  exemption  is  that  it  can  in  principle  be  justified  only  on 
grounds  of  equity,  grounds  that  would  not  appear  to  provide  a  basis  for  the  unique 
exemption  of  government  departments  from  taxation.  Our  final  consideration  is 
that  government  activity  of  any  kind  creates  demand  for  public  services  in  the  same 
way  that  demand  is  created  by  private  firms  and  individuals.  To  the  extent  that 
one  level  of  government  is  exempted  from  the  taxes  levied  by  another,  benefits  of 
such  services  are  conferred  without  relation  to  costs. 

65.  It  is  our  considered  opinion,  therefore,  that  the  federal  government  should 
pay  the  equivalent  of  full  provincial  taxes  and  that  provinces  should  assume  a 
similar  responsibility  with  respect  to  their  federal  tax  obligations.  We  believe  that 
the  implementation  of  this  viewpoint,  in  providing  identical  tax  treatment  of  govern- 
ment and  business,  will  facilitate  an  optimal  allocation  of  resources  between  the 
public  and  private  sectors  of  the  economy.  Furthermore,  the  consequently  enhanced 
integrity  of  both  the  federal  and  provincial  tax  base  can  only  promote  governmental 
consciousness  of  the  costs  of  public  services  and  the  simplicity  of  the  tax  system  as 
a  whole. 

66.  Our  lengthy  exposition  of  the  various  principles  we  consider  essential  to 
well-ordered  fiscal  relations  in  a  federal  scheme  can  now  be  brought  to  a  close. 
But  we  have  by  no  means  exhausted  the  vast  network  of  intergovernmental  relation- 
ships that  comprise  the  whole  of  the  Canadian  fiscal  system.  It  is  to  the  no  less 
important  domain  of  provincial-municipal  affairs  that  we  now  must  turn. 

41 


Intergovernmental  Fiscal  Relations 

OUR  PHILOSOPHY  OF  PROVINCIAL-MUNICIPAL  RELATIONS 
AND  ITS  FISCAL  IMPLICATIONS 

THE  NATURE  OF  THE  PROVINCIAL -MUNICIPAL  RELATIONSHIP 

67.  Unlike  federalism,  the  provincial-municipal  relationship  defies  simple  defi- 
nition. Perhaps  the  most  useful  starting  point  from  which  to  broach  its  nature  is 
to  compare  and  contrast  its  dimensions  with  those  of  federalism.  Let  us  begin  by 
drawing  the  contrasts. 

68.  Three  major  elements  of  contrast  between  federalism  and  the  provincial- 
municipal  realm  suggest  themselves  to  us.  First,  in  legal  terms,  the  federal-pro- 
vincial relationship  is  based  on  constitutional  law;  the  provincial-municipal  on 
statutory  law.  Second,  in  policy  terms,  the  federal-provincial  relationship  is  one 
of  equal  to  equal;  the  provincial-municipal  is  one  of  superior  to  subordinate.  Third, 
in  structural  terms,  the  federal-provincial  relationship  is  one  of  relative  simpUcity; 
the  provincial-municipal  is  highly  complex. 

69.  The  statutory  nature  of  provincial-municipal  relations  flows  directly  from 
the  British  North  America  Act  which  places  under  exclusive  provincial  jurisdiction 
"Municipal  institutions  in  the  Province".^*  Municipahties  are  accordingly  creatures 
of  the  province  and  a  province  is  legally  free  to  create,  modify  or  abolish  any  and  all 
units  of  local  government.  This  surely  offers  a  sharp  contrast  to  the  constitutional 
sanctity  accorded  to  provincial  entities  in  a  federal  system. 

70.  The  subordinate  status  of  municipal  institutions  in  terms  of  policy  flows 
directly  from  their  position  as  creatures  of  provincial  statutory  law.  Municipal 
tax  powers  and  spending  responsibilities  are  no  more  and  no  less  than  those  laid 
down  in  provincial  acts.  A  province  can  freely  choose  to  make  certain  public 
services  mandatory  at  the  local  level  and  others  merely  optional.  It  can  require 
municipalities  to  meet  specified  standards  of  performance.  It  can  limit  the  amount 
of,  and  otherwise  control,  the  borrowing  activities  of  municipalities  and  school 
boards.  A  province,  in  brief,  can  generally  supervise  and  direct  the  development 
of  municipal  public  policy.  This  again  offers  a  distinct  contrast  to  the  federal- 
provincial  sphere  where  neither  level  of  government  has  a  direct  responsibility  for 
the  conduct  of  the  other. 

7 1 .  The  structural  complexity  of  provincial-municipal  relations  by  comparison 
with  the  relative  simplicity  of  federalism  hardly  needs  belabouring.  The  latter 
relationship  involves  a  federal  government  and  ten  provinces.  The  former,  on  the 
other  hand,  involves  a  province  and  literally  hundreds  of  local  authorities,  some 
regional,  some  not,  some  of  a  general-purpose  nature — e.g.,  cities,  towns,  town- 
ships— some  specialized — e.g.,  conservation  authorities — and  all  differing  sub- 
stantially one  from  the  other  in  terms  of  area,  population  and  resources.  To  draw 
just  one  of  the  implications  of  this  major  contrast,  a  federal-provincial  conference 
can  take  place  in  the  intimate  personalized  atmosphere  characteristic  of  a  univer- 
sity seminar,  whereas  a  full-scale  provincial-municipal  conference  could  only  be 

"Section  92(8). 

42 


Chapter  2:  Paragraphs  67-75 

carried  on  under  conditions  resembling  a  lecture  whose  attendance  would  tax  the 
capacity  of  the  very  largest  auditorium. 

72.  Of  extreme  structural  complexity,  the  provincial-municipal  relationship  is 
one  of  local  subordination  to  provincial  authority,  couched  in  terms  of  statutory 
law.  Yet  for  all  its  differences  from  federaUsm,  it  has  important  elements  of 
similarity.  Within  the  provincial  scene,  municipalities  are  recognized  instruments 
of  diversity.  Their  existence  fosters  democratic  values  by  bringing  governmental 
institutions  to  the  individual's  doorstep.  They  can  promote  efficiency  through  a 
division  of  labour  that  enables  local  responsibility  to  be  met  locally.  As  such, 
municipalities  are  an  integral  part  of  a  multiple-level  political  system  both  as 
havens  of  democracy  and  as  vehicles  of  public  administration.  The  attendant  legal 
superiority  of  the  province  should  in  no  way  provide  any  licence  for  caprice. 
Municipalities,  by  virtue  of  their  intrinsic  contribution  to  responsible  democracy 
and  effective  administration,  have  an  integrity  of  their  own  which  partially  circum- 
scribes their  legally  inferior  status.  The  provincial-municipal  relationship  is 
accordingly  modified  from  one  of  pure  subordination  to  one  that  might  be  likened 
to  a  senior-junior  partnership. 

OUR  PHILOSOPHY  OF  PROVINCIAL -MUNICIPAL  RELATIONS 

73.  Our  philosophy  of  provincial-municipal  relations  is  grounded  in  the 
perspective  that  has  led  us  to  conclude  that  these  relations  closely  resemble  those 
of  a  senior-junior  partnership.  It  can  now  be  articulated  in  terms  of  four  principles 
which,  while  similar  in  number  to  the  principles  which  we  espouse  in  the  domain 
of  federalism,  differ  appreciably  in  content.  These  principles  we  have  chosen  to 
call  local  autonomy,  provincial  responsibility,  equalization  and  assistance. 

74.  By  the  principle  of  local  autonomy,  we  mean  that  the  dual  role  of  muni- 
cipal institutions  in  fostering  democratic  values  and  administrative  decentralization 
must  be  respected  and  encouraged.  This  aim  can  only  be  realized  if  a  well- 
organized  municipal  system  is  accorded  ample  scope  over  the  discharge  of  a 
number  of  important  functions.  Municipalities  should  be  accorded  a  wide  measure 
of  discretionary  authority  over  the  quantity  and  quality  of  the  public  services  en- 
trusted to  them,  and  equipped  with  sources  of  revenue  both  adequate  for  the 
discharge  of  their  spending  responsibilities  and  sufficient  to  ensure  direct  account- 
ability to  the  public.  Properly  understood,  the  principle  of  local  autonomy  is  not 
a  refuge  for  municipalities  too  small  or  weakly  organized  to  permit  the  responsible 
discharge  of  important  functions.  Nor  does  it  sanction  the  endless  multiplication 
of  special-purpose  authorities  constituted  for  the  provision  of  a  single  service, 
often  to  the  confusion  of  the  electorate  and  to  the  detriment  of  public  account- 
ability. Rather,  local  autonomy,  as  we  envisage  it,  is  both  a  safeguard  to  the  integ- 
rity of  municipal  democracy  and  efficiency  and  a  clarion  call  for  municipal 
institutions  capable  of  bringing  responsive  administration  to  all  parts  of  a  province. 

75.  We  believe  that  the  principle  of  local  autonomy  is  supported  rather  than 
contradicted  by  our  second  basic  principle,  that  of  provincial  responsibility.  This 
latter  principle  draws  on  the  incontrovertible  fact  that  municipalities  are  creatures 

43 


Intergovernmental  Fiscal  Relations 

of  the  province  and  legally  subject  to  provincial  statutes.  It  emphasizes,  however, 
that  the  considerable  power  vested  in  provincial  legislatures  should  only  be 
discharged  with  reference  to  an  abiding  and  pervasive  concern  for  the  promotion 
of  healthy  municipal  institutions.  Thus  the  power  of  a  province  to  create  muni- 
cipaHties  involves  a  heavy  responsibility  for  organizing  local  authorities  that  will 
embody  a  population,  area  and  resources  adequate  for  the  conduct  of  efficient 
government.  Viewed  in  the  above  light,  local  autonomy  and  provincial  respon- 
sibility are  indeed  mutually  complementary.  We  believe  that  this  compatibihty  is 
further  ensured  by  our  two  remaining  principles,  equalization  and  assistance. 

76.  Equalization,  one  of  our  basic  principles  of  federal-provincial  relations, 
returns  to  the  provincial-municipal  sphere  but  with  a  somewhat  different  connota- 
tion. Equalization  is,  of  course,  a  no  less  necessary  adjunct  of  local  autonomy 
than  it  is  of  provincial  autonomy,  in  that  all  municipalities  must  have  the  financial 
resources  to  provide  minimally  satisfactory  levels  of  public  service.  But  in  the 
provincial-municipal  realm,  equalization  also  becomes  a  highly  important  con- 
comitant of  a  province's  statutory  power  over  local  institutions.  Because  a 
province  has  the  power  to  create  municipalities,  it  is  in  a  position  to  assess  the 
desirability  of  pooling  tax  resources  through  larger  units  of  local  government  as  an 
alternative  to  equalization  grants.  Furthermore,  if  a  province  has  the  authority 
not  only  to  devolve  mandatory  functions  upon  local  government  but  also  to 
prescribe  standards  of  municipal  performance,  the  need  to  take  account  of  inter- 
municipal  differences  in  fiscal  capacity  is  clear  and  unambiguous. 

77.  Similar  considerations  highlight  the  importance  of  our  final  principle,  that 
of  provincial  technical  and  administrative  assistance.  Here  we  mean  to  emphasize 
a  primary  consequence  of  general  provincial  responsibility.  This  is  that  a  province, 
in  addition  to  fostering  viable  municipal  institutions,  must  be  ready  to  provide 
practical  administrative  guidance  and  aid  whenever  it  chooses  to  exercise  its 
superior  powers  in  the  municipal  realm.  To  cite  but  two  examples,  provincial 
legislation  calling,  let  us  say,  for  mandatory  community  planning  is  an  affront  to 
common  sense  unless  it  also  makes  available  concrete  technical  assistance  on  how 
to  organize  a  local  planning  board  or  department.  In  a  similar  vein,  provincial 
efforts  bent  on  securing  greater  uniformity  in  assessment  will  be  futile  unless 
they  are  accompanied  by  a  well-compiled  assessment  manual  and  a  program  to 
train  assessors  in  its  use. 

78.  At  this  point  we  should  make  it  plain  that  in  espousing  the  principle  of 
assistance,  we  do  not  advocate  a  provincial  tutelage  over  municipalities.  Local 
autonomy,  defined  simply  as  a  wide  measure  of  discretionary  municipal  authority, 
well  grounded  on  close  accountability  to  the  local  electorate,  remains  a  prime 
requisite  for  a  healthy  municipal  system.  Accordingly,  the  principle  of  provincial 
assistance  should  be  understood  as  looking  toward  stronger  municipal  government. 
We  would  regard  provincial  measures  that  sapped  municipalities  of  their  vitality 
as  a  harmful  disturbance  of  the  provincial-municipal  climate  that  we  advocate,  a 
climate  in  which  local  autonomy  and  provincial  responsibility  provide  mutual 
reinforcement. 

44 


Chapter  2:  Paragraphs  76-83 

79.  Four  important  principles,  then,  comprise  our  philosophy  of  provincial- 
municipal  relations.  There  now  remains  the  difficult  task  of  applying  these  prin- 
ciples to  the  intergovernmental  division  of  expenditure  functions  and  revenue 
powers,  to  grants,  to  local  government  organization  and  to  provincial-municipal 
tax  liabilities. 

THE  DIVISION  OF  EXPENDITURE  FUNCTIONS 

80.  Local  autonomy  demands  that  municipahties  have  important  functions  to 
perform.  A  provincial-municipal  system  that  leaves  to  the  discretion  of  local 
authorities  little  more  than  sidewalk  construction  and  the  erection  of  street  signs 
would  be  a  system  in  which  municipalities  had  become  empty  shells,  drained  of 
significance  and  operating  in  an  atmosphere  of  public  apathy.  Any  proper  provin- 
cial-municipal division  of  spending  functions,  therefore,  must  leave  in  local  hands 
a  multiplicity  of  major  expenditure  responsibilities. 

81.  The  provincial-municipal  division  of  functions  has  in  fact  varied  sub- 
stantially over  time.  Certain  public  expenditures  that  had  their  beginnings  at  the 
municipal  level — for  example,  welfare — have  since  been  moved  in  part  to  higher 
levels  of  government.  Yet  other  and  new  responsibilities,  many  of  them  the  con- 
sequence of  urbanization  and  technological  change,  have  recently  devolved  upon 
local  authorities.  Urban  renewal  provides  a  good  example.  The  fluctuating  nature 
of  the  provincial-municipal  division  of  spending  responsibilities  is  testimony  to  the 
critically  important  role  of  local  authorities  in  our  governmental  system.  That 
many  functions  have  their  beginnings  at  the  municipal  level  is  in  part  due  to  the 
fact  that  the  local  authority,  as  the  unit  of  government  closest  to  the  people,  is 
often  the  first  to  respond  to  newly  felt  needs. 

82.  It  is  reasonable  to  expect  the  provincial-municipal  division  of  spending 
responsibilities  to  alter  periodically  in  response  to  changing  needs  and  circum- 
stances. This  division  will  of  itself  tend  to  be  more  flexible  than  that  which  prevails 
in  the  domain  of  federalism  because  of  the  absence  of  constitutional  restraints.  Not 
only  can  spending  responsibilities  be  readily  shifted  between  the  province  and 
local  authorities;  they  can  also  be  shifted  by  the  province  among  various  kinds  of 
local  authorities,  especially  between  regional  units  of  municipal  government  on 
the  one  hand  and  cities,  towns,  townships  and  villages  on  the  other.  Our  principal 
concern  is  to  ensure  that,  whatever  its  exact  dimension  at  any  given  point  in  time, 
the  provincial-municipal  division  of  spending  responsibiUties  be  such  that  local 
discretion  over  a  number  of  important  functions  is  assured.  The  principle  of  local 
autonomy  demands  no  less,  and  requires  that  such  changes  should  evolve  from 
appropriate  intergovernmental  discussion  of  the  issues. 

83.  We  believe  that  all  those  services  whose  benefits  are  of  primarily  local 
concern  should  be  provided  by  local  authorities.  Such  services,  of  course,  include 
police  and  fire  protection,  the  construction,  maintenance  and  lighting  of  local 
streets,  and  recreation  and  community  facilities.  But  we  are  of  the  further  opinion 
that  certain  other  services,  whose  provision  is  as  much  a  matter  of  general  as  of 
local  concern,  can  constitute  in  important  respects  a  local  responsibility  as  well, 

45 


Intergovernmental  Fiscal  Relations 

especially  if  they  are  under  the  jurisdiction  of  sufficiently  large  units  of  government. 
Health,  public  libraries  and  the  construction  and  maintenance  of  access  roads  are 
examples  of  such  services.  Our  motivation  in  advocating  local  responsibility  for 
these  services  stems  from  the  twin  underpinnings  of  local  autonomy  and  efficient 
administration.  Because  larger,  perhaps  regional  units  of  local  government  auto- 
matically pool  the  financial  resources  of  a  more  diverse  and  populated  area,  they 
make  possible  levels  of  service  not  otherwise  attainable  by  local  authorities.  At 
the  same  time,  such  units  ensure  that  the  functions  assigned  to  them  will  conform 
more  closely  to  locally  expressed  wishes  than  they  would  if  the  functions  in 
question  were  assigned  to  the  province. 

84.  Our  concern  for  local  autonomy  in  the  provincial-municipal  division  of 
spending  functions,  to  be  properly  understood,  must  be  viewed  from  the  perspec- 
tive contributed  by  the  principle  of  provincial  responsibility.  Provincial  respon- 
sibility should  apply  with  particular  force  to  those  services  that  are  of  both  general 
and  local  concern.  Here  the  principle  extends  to  minimum  standards,  to  forms  of 
administration,  and  even  to  the  creation  of  appropriately  designed  goverimiental 
units. 

85.  At  this  point,  the  applicability  of  the  principles  of  equalization  and  of 
provincial  assistance  should  be  obvious.  Particularly  in  the  realm  of  services  that 
are  of  general  concern,  equalization,  because  of  the  principle  of  provincial  respon- 
sibility, will  have  a  vastly  greater  role  than  it  plays  in  federal-provincial  relations. 
For  its  part,  provincial  assistance  in  the  administrative  and  organizational  realm 
occupies  a  key  position. 

THE  DIVISION  OF  REVENUE  SOURCES 

86.  Just  as  the  principle  of  local  autonomy  demands  that  municipalities  have 
important  functions  to  perform,  so  also  does  it  dictate  that  these  entities  have 
revenue  sources  of  corresponding  adequacy.  Since  the  provincial-municipal  division 
of  revenue  has  no  constitutional  base,  it  is  the  principle  of  provincial  responsibility 
which  dictates  that  the  province  provide  its  municipahties  with  an  adequate  revenue 
system. 

87.  As  a  matter  of  long  tradition,  the  provincial-municipal  division  of  revenue 
sources  has  left  the  tax  on  real  property  in  organized  municipalities  to  the  exclusive 
use  of  local  authorities.  That  the  property  tax  is  peculiarly  well  suited  to  municipal 
use  is  attested  to  both  by  history  and  by  common  practice  in  most  of  the  indus- 
trialized nations  of  the  west.  The  relative  stabihty  and  immobility  of  the  tax  base, 
the  simplicity  of  collection  procedures,  and  the  ease  with  which  rate  changes  can 
be  legislated  to  accommodate  changing  spending  obligations:  these  are  the  mani- 
fest qualities  which  have  made  the  property  tax  the  basic  local  levy.  We  recog- 
nize these  qualities  and  wish  simply  to  single  out  two  other  characteristics  which 
add  to  the  appropriateness  of  the  property  tax  as  the  bed-rock  of  municipal  finance. 
First,  there  is  no  question  but  that  the  high  visibility  of  this  tax  enhances  that 
essential  component  of  effective  local  autonomy,  public  accountability,  even 
though  on  occasion  this  may  lead  to  false  economies.    And  second,  the  property 

46 


Chapter  2:  Paragraphs  84-90 

tax,  although  imperfectly  reflecting  benefits  received,  can  be  a  useful  if  rough 
index  for  gauging  the  propriety  of  existing  provincial-municipal  divisions  of  spend- 
ing responsibilities.  It  can  translate  the  often  vague  idea  of  a  service  that  is 
"primarily  local"  into  the  somewhat  more  concrete  notion  of  a  service  that  is  of 
benefit  to  persons  as  owners  or  occupants  of  real  property  and  hence  one  that 
should  be  provided  locally. 

88.  The  above  remark  is  not  meant,  of  course,  to  convey  the  impression  that 
we  share  in  the  viewpoint,  popular  in  certain  circles,  that  the  property  tax  should 
be  used  to  finance  only  those  services  that  are  directly  related  to  property.  On  the 
contrary,  we  believe  that  there  is  strong  justification  for  applying  the  property  tax 
to  services  that  are  indirectly  related  to  property  as  well,  both  because  the  dis- 
tinction between  direct  and  indirect  benefits  is  highly  tenuous  and  because  a  theory 
of  direct  benefits,  even  if  workable,  would  be  unduly  confining  and  hence  injurious 
to  the  principle  of  local  autonomy.  At  its  best,  the  notion  of  direct  versus  indirect 
benefits  will  provide  a  guide  to  what  portion  of  a  service  should  be  financed  through 
the  property  tax  and  what  through  other  means. 

89.  This  brings  us  to  the  thorny  question  of  what  revenues  other  than  the 
property  tax  should  accrue  to  the  local  level.  The  principle  of  local  autonomy, 
with  its  vital  connotation  of  public  accountability,  inclines  us  philosophically  to 
favour  the  maximum  degree  of  municipal  responsibility  in  the  raising  of  revenue. 
We  are  nevertheless  conscious  of  the  fact  that  the  property  tax  yield  tends  to 
respond  rather  more  slowly  to  economic  growth  than  the  yields  of  other  taxes, 
notably  those  on  income  and  consumption.  Because  such  a  large  proportion  of 
municipal  expenditure  is  a  direct  function  of  economic  growth  and  of  its  principal 
concomitant,  urbanization,  excessive  reliance  on  the  real  property  tax  can  leave 
municipal  government  ill  equipped  to  meet  its  service  responsibilities.  In  contrast 
to  that  of  the  senior  levels  of  government,  the  structure  of  municipal  finance 
reveals  a  basic  imbalance  in  that  it  couples  a  relatively  stable  revenue  base  with 
rapidly  expanding  expenditure  requirements.  We  have  accordingly  paid  more 
than  passing  attention  to  the  development  of  local  non-property  taxes,  as  the  most 
casual  perusal  of  this  Report  will  make  evident.  Our  research,  however,  has  im- 
pressed us  with  the  major  difficulties — in  equity,  in  collection,  and  in  the  allocation 
of  proceeds — that  adhere  to  municipal  reliance  upon  any  major  non-property  tax 
field,  whether  in  the  form  of  provincially  shared  levies  or  not,  unless  larger  units 
of  government  are  organized  where  appropriate.  We  believe  that  the  principle 
of  local  autonomy  dictates  that  every  possible  effort  be  made  to  overcome  these 
difficulties,  and  that  the  principle  of  provincial  responsibility  makes  the  quest  for 
governmental  units  suited  to  the  introduction  of  non-property  taxes  a  matter  for 
vigorous  joint  endeavour  by  both  levels  of  government. 

90.  Attempts  to  broaden  the  municipal  revenue  base,  however  well  motivated 
and  conscientiously  undertaken,  do  not  comprise  a  substitute  for  the  strengthening 
of  the  property  tax  itself.  Here  we  wish  to  call  particular  attention  to  our  principle 
of  provincial  assistance.  Deliberate  provincial  policies  designed  to  improve  muni- 
cipal assessment  practices  and  collection  procedures  are  indispensable.    Another 

47 


Intergovernmental  Fiscal  Relations 

important  area,  reflected  in  the  provincial  statutory  regulation  of  such  activities, 
is  the  thorny  problem  of  inter-municipal  competition  for  high-yield  commercial 
and  residential  developments.  Such  competition  tends  to  impinge  severely  on 
effective  planning  and  on  the  most  efficient  allocation  of  resources.  It  creates 
tendencies  toward  what  might  be  called  "municipal  protectionism"  quite  as  harmful 
to  economic  and  social  well-being  as  those  involved  in  provincial  protectionism. 
The  answer  to  such  cut-throat  competition  for  a  favourable  municipal  tax  base, 
no  less  than  to  the  improvement  of  property  tax  administration,  lies  in  provincial 
policies  designed  to  rationalize  municipal  institutions  and  improve  the  local  revenue 
base. 

THE  ROLE  OF  GRANTS 

91.  The  difficulties  inherent  in  devising  suitable  municipal  non-property  taxes 
constitute  a  major  reason  for  the  importance  of  provincial  grants  to  municipalities. 
Moreover,  in  the  discharge  of  its  municipal  responsibilities,  the  province  has 
utilized  such  grants  as  one  of  its  important  instruments.  The  discussion  that  follows 
will  make  use  of  the  threefold  division  of  grant  payments  developed  earlier  in  the 
context  of  federal-provincial  finance,  namely  revenue  deficiency  grants,  equaliza- 
tion grants  and  stimulation  grants. 

Revenue  Deficiency  Grants 

92.  Unconditional  grants  designed  to  make  up  across-the-board  deficiencies 
in  municipal  revenue  have  a  place  only  inasmuch  as  there  is  a  need  to  supplement 
the  property  tax  and  in  so  far  as  this  need  cannot  be  met  through  local  non- 
property  taxes.  Since  we  place  a  high  value  on  the  close  public  accountability  that 
results  from  the  greatest  possible  municipal  responsibility  in  the  raising  of  revenue, 
we  view  deficiency  grants  as  a  second-best  alternative  in  principle.  But  because  of 
the  difficulties  that  impede  a  broadening  of  the  local  tax  base — difficulties  to  which 
we  have  just  had  occasion  to  refer — we  recognize  that  revenue  deficiency  grants  are 
an  indispensable  adjunct  of  local  finance.  We  wish  to  stress,  however,  that  we  con- 
sider the  case  for  deficiency  grants  to  be  practically  oriented  rather  than  philosophic- 
ally sound. 

Equalization  Grants 

93.  The  case  for  lessening  gross  inter-municipal  disparities  in  fiscal  capacity, 
if  properly  put,  is  unassailable.  The  principle  of  local  autonomy  can  hardly  be 
translated  into  reality  if  certain  municipalities  lack  the  resources  to  meet  the  costs 
of  their  basic  services.  Moreover,  the  principle  of  provincial  responsibility,  with 
its  strong  concomitant  of  provincial  concern  for  the  provision  of  certain  services  at 
stated  minimal  levels  of  performance,  lends  forceful  support  to  the  development 
of  equalization  in  local  finance. 

94.  While  equalization  has  a  considerable  role  in  the  provincial-municipal 
scene,  it  remains  subject  to  a  cautionary  note  concerning  the  danger  of  inducing 
distortions  in  the  economic  allocation  of  resources.  In  particular,  we  believe  that 
equalization  grants  are  least  likely  to  run  counter  to  a  rational  allocation  of 

48 


Chapter  2:  Paragraphs  91-97 

resources  in  the  provincial-municipal  realm  if  they  conform  to  three  basic  rules. 
First,  equalization  grants  are  not  a  substitute  for  municipal  entities'  being  of  viable 
size.  Second,  minimal  standards  of  performance  laid  down  by  provincial  legisla- 
tion should  not  seek  levels  of  services  that  lie  beyond  what  is  socially  acceptable 
at  any  point  in  time  as  a  reasonable  minimum  standard.  Third,  as  to  those  services 
whose  benefits  to  property  owners  are  unquestionably  direct,  the  need  for  equaliza- 
tion is  precluded  in  all  but  the  very  poorest  municipalities.  This  is  because  the 
value  of  property,  and  hence  the  municipal  tax  base,  is  itself  a  fair  index  of  the 
acceptable  standard  of  services  needed.  Thus  an  intensively  developed  residential 
neighbourhood  abutting  an  explosives  factory  has  both  the  resources  and  the  need 
to  provide  an  up-to-date  fire  department  manned  by  a  full-time  force  using  the 
most  technically  advanced  equipment.  A  sparsely  populated  rural  municipality,  on 
the  other  hand,  will  tend  to  have  a  lesser  need  for  fire  protection  services,  matching 
its  slimmer  resources. 

95.  Equalization  grants,  then,  are  most  appropriate  when  they  are  made  in 
recognition  of  the  desirability  of  enabling  municipalities  to  meet  performance 
standards  of  minimum  social  acceptability  in  services  whose  benefits  to  individuals 
as  property  owners  are  either  indirect  or  intangible.  Such  grants  may,  of  course, 
be  either  conditional  or  unconditional.  Our  assessment  of  which  form  is  more 
desirable  must  await  discussion  of  the  role  of  stimulation  grants. 

Stimulation  Grants 

96.  Grants  designed  to  encourage  municipalities  to  provide  certain  services 
according  to  more  or  less  closely  stipulated  standards  constitute  a  logical  exten- 
sion of  the  principle  of  provincial  responsibility,  which  gives  a  province  scope 
within  which  to  guide  the  setting  of  expenditure  priorities  at  the  municipal  level. 
Recognition  of  this  point  is  not,  to  be  sure,  approbation  of  its  indiscriminate  applica- 
tion. We  believe  that  there  exist  two  realistic  limits  on  the  extension  of  conditional 
or  stimulation  grants  to  municipalities.  The  first  is  the  point  at  which  such  grants 
involve  municipal  budgetary  distortions  such  as  to  impinge  seriously  on  local 
autonomy.  The  second  is  where  grant  programs  have  become  sufiiciently  numerous 
to  pose  serious  administrative  problems  and  to  exceed  the  capacity  of  local 
authorities  to  take  advantage  of  their  existence.  An  important  test  of  the 
adequacy  of  a  provincial  stimulation  grant  system,  therefore,  is  a  combination  of 
restraint  and  simplicity.  Conditional  grants  should  extend  only  to  those  programs 
in  which  municipal  stimulation  is  a  matter  of  genuine  provincial  interest.  Such 
grants  are,  of  course,  not  the  only  appropriate  means  of  stimulating  particular 
municipal  functions  in  which  the  province  has  an  interest.  It  follows  that  all  such 
grants  should  be  reviewed  from  time  to  time  with  a  view  toward  determining  the 
usefulness  of  their  continued  existence. 

97.  However  carefully  rationalized  in  terms  of  structure  and  administation,  no 
system  of  conditional  grants  can  be  properly  devised  without  reference  to  inter- 
municipal  disparities  in  fiscal  capacity.  We  have  become  acutely  conscious  of  the 
inequities  that  can  result  from  stimulation  grants  made  according  to  a  so-called 
"flat  rate",  that  is  to  say  according  to  a  stated  percentage  of  total  program  costs. 

49 


Intergovernmental  Fiscal  Relations 

Flat-rate  stimulation  grants  are,  as  is  well  known,  a  matter  of  common  provincial 
practice.  The  inequities  that  flow  from  grants  of  this  type  result  from  the  fact  that 
such  grants  can  have  two  quite  different  effects.  One,  the  "incentive  effect",  is 
the  normal  effect  obtained  when  a  municipality  that  has  not  previously  provided 
the  grant-aided  service,  or  has  provided  it  at  a  standard  below  that  envisaged  by 
the  provincial  grant  program,  takes  advantage  of  the  assistance  offered  by  the 
province  and  consequently  ties  up  whatever  local  tax  resources  are  required  to 
match  provincial  funds.  The  other,  a  "substitution  effect",  occurs  in  municipalities 
that  have  already  provided  the  service  at  acceptable  standards  prior  to  the  in- 
ception of  the  grant.  For  such  municipalities,  the  new  grant  provides  not  a 
stimulant  but  a  subsidy  that  can  be  applied  either  to  the  provision  of  additional 
units  of  the  grant-aided  service,  or  to  other  items  of  expenditure,  or  to  a  reduction 
in  property  taxes.  The  result  is  that  stimulation  grants,  depending  on  their  effect, 
can  create  a  dual  type  of  discrimination.  One  arises  from  the  additional  budgetary 
discretion  which  a  municipality  enjoying  a  substitution  effect  gains  by  comparison 
with  the  municipality  subject  to  an  incentive  effect.  The  second  is  due  to  the  fact 
that  the  municipality  that  already  provided  the  grant-aided  service,  and  hence 
enjoys  the  substitution  effect,  is  very  likely  a  wealthier  municipality  than  its 
counterpart  which,  not  having  provided  the  service  previously,  falls  under  the 
incentive  effect.  In  any  system  that  incorporates  a  multiplicity  of  conditional 
grants,  serious  problems  of  equity  inevitably  arise. 

98.  Since  stimulation  grants  by  virtue  of  their  very  effect  can  accentuate  inter- 
municipal  differences  in  fiscal  capacity,  equalization  provisions  have  a  decided 
role  to  play  in  grants  of  a  conditional  type.  But  because  we  believe  that  stimula- 
tion grants  should  be  limited  in  number,  and  also  because  all  stimulation  grants 
are  not  necessarily  amenable  to  equalization,  it  is  doubtless  desirable  to  incorporate 
certain  equaUzation  provisions  either  into  unconditional  grants  made  in  recognition 
of  across-the-board  deficiencies  in  municipal  revenue,  or  into  a  non-property 
municipal  tax  should  one  prove  feasible.  The  extent  to  which  equalization  should 
be  carried  in  either  case  is,  of  course,  subject  to  the  limitations  discussed  earlier. 

99.  The  task  of  devising  a  rational  provincial-municipal  grant  structure,  whether 
with  reference  to  revenue  deficiency,  stimulation  or  equalization,  is  appreciably 
more  complex  than  that  of  improving  grant  practices  in  the  federal-provincial 
domain.  This  is  largely  because  differences  in  municipal  population,  service  needs 
and  fiscal  capacity  are  in  fact  much  greater  than  those  that  prevail  among  provinces. 
In  their  most  extreme  form  inter-municipal  discrepancies  may  well  be  insuperable 
obstacles  in  the  path  of  improved  grant  policies.  It  is  at  this  point  that  the  viability 
of  municipal  institutions  themselves  must  come  under  close  scrutiny. 

THE  PROVINCE  AND  LOCAL  GOVERNMENT  ORGANIZATION 

100.  As  we  have  already  had  occasion  to  point  out,  the  principle  of  local 
autonomy  is  not  a  haven  for  municipalities  so  small  or  weakly  organized  that  they 
cannot  discharge  their  functions  in  efficient  fashion.  On  the  contrary,  local 
autonomy  stresses  the  importance  of  strong  and  responsible  municipal  institutions 
whose  establishment  and  promotion  are  an  important  provincial  responsibility. 

50 


Chapter  2:  Paragraphs  98-106 

101.  The  strength  of  a  local  unit  of  government  is  normally  determined  by  the 
extent  to  which  population  and  resources  are  balanced  within  a  given  area.  We  are 
of  the  firm  opinion,  therefore,  that  a  philosophy  of  provincial-municipal  fiscal 
relations  cannot  pretend  to  be  adequate  unless  it  takes  into  account  provincial 
responsibility  for  the  structure  of  municipal  institutions  and  the  consequences  of 
boundary  organization  for  local  autonomy. 

102.  The  notion  that  a  unit  of  government  can  be  too  big  to  function  in  an 
efficient  and  responsible  fashion  can  be  traced  back  to  the  earliest  political  thinkers 
in  the  history  of  western  civilization.  It  is  precisely  to  avoid  the  more  vexing 
problems  of  bigness  that  most  modern  democratic  states  foster  the  existence  of 
municipal  institutions.  Yet  there  also  exists  a  contrary  notion,  firmly  rooted  in 
practical  experience,  that  a  unit  of  government  can  be  too  small  in  relation  to  the 
minimum  size  necessary  for  the  most  efficient  discharge  of  local  functions. 

103.  We  have  been  impressed  by  the  number  of  municipal  units  that  lack  the 
necessary  area,  population  and  resources  needed  to  achieve  financial  and  adminis- 
trative adequacy,  the  essentials  of  functioning  autonomy.  The  plight  of  such 
municipalities  is  indeed  a  doleful  one.  Their  revenue  base,  pitifully  slim  in  many 
instances,  is  further  eroded  by  poor  assessment  and  collection  procedures.  Among 
such  small  municipalities  can  be  found  particularly  strong  pressures  towards  cut- 
throat competition  for  business  assessment,  to  the  detriment  of  sound  zoning  and 
planning  practices.  The  effectiveness  of  such  important  spending  functions  as 
health  and  welfare  becomes  dissipated  because  of  size  too  small  to  support  the 
necessary  range  and  standards  of  field  services.  In  addition,  the  ability  of  the 
province  to  be  of  assistance,  whether  through  grants  or  administrative  guidance,  is 
hampered  by  extremes  of  poverty  and  smallness  of  scale  that  defy  adaptability  to 
policies  designed  with  more  viable  units  in  mind. 

104.  We  are  likewise  impressed  by  the  extent  to  which  piecemeal  solutions  to 
boundary  problems  tend  to  be  little  better  than  the  deficiencies  they  are  designed 
to  correct.  Ad  hoc  authorities,  such  as  those  created  in  the  health  and  conservation 
fields,  provide  governmental  units  of  sufficient  size  at  the  expense  of  divorcing  public 
expenditure  from  taxing  responsibility.  Worse  still,  such  authorities  induce  growing 
reliance  on  appointed  or  indirectly  elected  officials  to  the  detriment  of  the  democratic 
practices  that  surely  lie  at  the  heart  of  true  local  autonomy. 

105.  As  a  result  of  the  above-described  circumstances,  it  has  become  our 
considered  opinion  that,  in  the  interest  of  local  autonomy,  provincial  responsibility 
for  revision  in  municipal  boundaries  has  become  inescapable.  There  exist  two 
possible  courses  of  action.  One  involves  the  dissolution  of  certain  existing  local 
units  in  favour  of  new  and  larger  municipalities.  The  other  is  a  matter  of  fostering 
across  the  whole  province  a  regional  tier  of  local  government  that  would  be  directly 
accountable  for  the  performance  of  certain  services  whose  effective  discharge  is 
dependent  on  a  relatively  large  population  and  area.  We  proceed  to  comment  very 
briefly  on  each. 

106.  New  and  larger  municipalities  can  provide  an  answer  to  many  of  the 
problems  just  discussed.  They  can  promote  economies  of  scale,  provide  specialized 

51 


Intergovernmental  Fiscal  Relations 

services  not  otherwise  available,  and  achieve  a  needed  degree  of  equalization  by 
pooling  the  taxable  resources  of  a  wide  area.  We  do  recognize,  however,  the  exist- 
ence of  circumstances — not  all  of  them  valid — that  can  bar  advance  along  this 
particular  avenue  of  reform.  To  take  but  one  admittedly  extreme  example,  an 
isolated  municipality  with  but  a  small  contiguous  population  virtually  defies  en- 
largement. Viewed  in  this  light  the  replacement  of  existing  municipalities  by  larger 
ones,  while  both  feasible  and  desirable  in  many  cases,  cannot  be  deemed  to  exclude 
other  approaches. 

107.  A  second  or  regional  tier  of  local  government  is  not  entirely  a  substitute 
for  new  and  larger  municipalities;  indeed,  it  may  usefully  complement  their  develop- 
ment. In  any  event,  it  beckons  as  a  full-fledged  reform  in  its  own  right.  Even  in  a 
situation  where  all  municipalities  were  so  constituted  as  to  offer  generally  viable 
local  government,  there  would  remain  certain  functions,  of  which  roads,  health 
and  welfare  would  be  examples,  whose  effective  discharge  might  well  continue  to 
be  circumscribed  owing  to  lack  of  sufficient  population  and  taxable  resources. 
Here  regional  government  provides  a  reasonable  answer  by  providing  the  advantages 
of  a  large  municipal  entity  for  the  services  over  which  it  is  assigned  jurisdiction. 
Regional  government  is  sometimes  criticized  by  those  who  contend  that,  with  three 
levels  of  government,  federal,  provincial  and  municipal,  the  nation  is  already 
overgoverned.  But  this  line  of  reasoning  completely  overlooks  the  simple  fact  that 
the  practical  necessity  for  regional  government  is  such  that  this  second  level  of  local 
administration  is  historically  grounded  in  the  county  and  has  also  been  permitted 
and  even  encouraged  to  develop  in  an  ad  hoc  form.  Present  ad  hoc  authorities, 
however,  constitute  nothing  more  or  less  than  regional  government  on  a  narrowly 
specialized,  fractionalized  and  disjointed  basis,  regional  government  erected  at  the 
expense  of  public  accountability  and  direct  responsibility.  It  follows  that  the 
creation  of  comprehensive  regional  governments,  combining  within  themselves 
adequate  tax  powers  and  spending  responsibilities  and  directly  responsible  to  the 
electorate,  can  be  a  step  in  the  direction  of  better  government  rather  than  more 
government. 

108.  We  strongly  favour  the  fostering  of  larger  and  more  viable  units  of  local 
government,  regional  or  otherwise.  We  take  this  stand  not  primarily  on  administra- 
tive grounds  and  certainly  not  in  capitulation  to  the  inevitability  of  George  Orwell's 
rapidly  approaching  1984.  Rather,  we  take  it  in  the  interest  of  securing  strong 
local  authorities,  thereby  preserving  and  enhancing  local  autonomy  and  democratic 
government. 

THE  TAXATION  OF  GOVERNMENT  ENTITIES 

109.  Again  because  principles  are  involved,  we  wish,  as  we  did  in  our  treatment 
of  federal-provincial  finance,  to  descend  into  the  very  specific  realm  of  the  tax 
treatment  of  governmental  entities.  By  traditional  practice,  the  Province  of  Ontario 
has  exempted  itself  from  municipal  taxation.  In  a  reciprocal  vein,  the  provincial 
government  has  also  been  willing  to  grant  municipalities  either  exemptions  or 
rebates  on  provincial  taxation.  And  municipal  property  located  within  the  boun- 
daries of  another  local  jurisdiction  has  likewise  been  exempt. 

52 


k 


Chapter  2:  Paragraphs  107-1 14 

1 10.  Since  1952,  Ontario  has  made  grants  in  lieu  of  municipal,  but  not  school, 
property  taxes  on  a  limited  range  of  provincially  owned  property.  As  for  provincial 
Crown  agencies,  only  the  Hydro-Electric  Power  Commission  pays  grants  in  lieu  of 
property  taxes  for  both  school  and  municipal  purposes.  Much  Hydro  property, 
however,  is  exempt  from  taxation,  and  its  grants-in-lieu,  which  are  related  to  its 
taxable  properties  only,  are  paid  in  relation  to  a  statutory  assessment  of  those 
properties.  Other  Crown  agencies,  such  as  the  Liquor  Control  Board  and  the 
Province  of  Ontario  Savings  Office,  pay  grants  solely  in  lieu  of  the  municipal  levy. 

111.  Both  because  they  derive  benefits  from  the  local  jurisdictions  in  which 
they  are  situated  and  because  they  are  engaged  in  business  transactions,  provincial 
Crown  agencies  should  pay  full  grants  in  lieu  of  both  municipal  and  school  taxes 
and  be  assessed  in  accordance  with  the  same  principles  as  prevail  for  private  busi- 
ness property.  Exemption  of  Crown  agencies,  whether  partial  or  complete,  has 
added  unnecessarily  to  the  financial  problems  of  municipalities  and  school  boards. 
Furthermore,  the  resulting  advantage  accruing  to  these  entities  in  competition  with 
private  business  has  no  justification  in  terms  either  of  equity  or  of  economics. 

112.  Other  provincial  property,  in  so  far  as  it  creates  the  same  demands  for 
local  services  as  private  residential  and  commercial  entities,  has  no  sounder  a  case 
for  exemption.  Provincial  buildings  require  sanitation  and  related  services  no  less 
than  others.  Provincial  employees  strain  local  transportation  and  educational 
facilities  no  less  than  their  business  counterparts.  Full  provincial  payment  in  lieu 
of  all  local  taxes  is  hence  the  only  logical  policy.  And  by  extension  of  the  same 
argument,  municipal  property,  such  as  hydro  installations  situated  in  other  juris- 
dictions, should  meet  all  property  tax  liabilities. 

113.  Just  as  we  advocate  full  provincial  payment  of  all  local  taxes,  so  also  do 
we  favour  provincial  taxation  of  local  entities.  The  present  exemption  and  rebate 
provisions  which  the  provincial  retail  sales  tax,  to  take  but  one  example,  extends 
to  municipalities  and  school  boards,  only  serve  to  complicate  administration  and 
enforcement.  If  local  entities  are  in  need  of  financial  aid,  proper  assistance  should 
be  in  the  form  of  revised  provincial  grants  and  not  at  the  expense  of  the  provincial 
tax  structure.  In  short,  we  favour  the  demise  of  all  forms  of  intergovernmental  tax 
immunity,  which  serves  only  to  undermine  sound  taxation  practices. 

OUR  PHILOSOPHY  OF  PROVINCIAL-SCHOOL  BOARD  RELATIONS 
AND  ITS  FISCAL  IMPLICATIONS 

PRINCIPLES  OF  PROVINCIAI^SCHOOL  BOARD  RELATIONS 

114.  We  have  undertaken  to  enunciate  our  philosophy  of  provincial-school 
board  relations  in  isolation  from  our  discussion  of  the  provincial-municipal  realm 
partly  because  of  the  peculiar  financial  and  economic  importance  of  education  but 
more  especially  because  school  boards  occupy  a  position  somewhat  different  from 
that  held  by  other  local  authorities.  Thus  they  are  not  taxing  authorities,  but  instead 
raise  their  revenue  requirements  through  requisitions  on  local  councils.  A  further 
difference  is  found  in  the  fact  that  those  boards  charged  with  the  administration  of 


53 


Intergovernmental  Fiscal  Relations 

the  so-called  "separate"  schools  enjoy  a  certain  constitutional  sanctity  not  shared 
by  any  other  local  authorities  under  the  British  North  America  Act,  1867,  Section 
93  of  which  entrenches  the  provisions  of  The  Separate  Schools  Act  of  1863.  Finally, 
there  is  the  obvious  difference  that  in  contrast  to  local  councils,  school  boards 
specialize  in  the  discharge  of  one  particular  function,  education,  which  is  more 
fully  a  shared  responsibility  of  provincial  and  local  government  than  any  municipal 
activity. 

115.  We  proceed,  then,  fully  conscious  of  the  distinctive  position  of  school 
boards  within  the  governmental  structure.  Distinctions  aside,  school  boards  do  of 
course  remain  units  of  local  government.  As  such  we  believe  that  the  provincial- 
school  board  relationship  can  be  analysed  in  terms  of  the  four  principles  developed 
in  the  municipal  context,  that  is  to  say  local  autonomy,  provincial  responsibility, 
equalization  and  assistance.  These  principles  we  presently  venture  to  apply  to  the 
division  of  expenditure  responsibilities  and  revenue  sources,  to  grants  and  to  school 
board  organization. 

THE  DIVISION  OF  EXPENDITURE  RESPONSIBILITIES 

1 16.  The  above  heading  is  something  of  a  misnomer  in  that  expenditure  respon- 
sibilities for  education  are  more  shared  than  divided.  The  province  and  school 
boards  share  in  common  the  financial  burden  of  nearly  all  facets  of  the  educational 
system,  including  construction,  teachers'  salaries  and  school  maintenance.  Yet  on 
close  inspection  a  certain  division  of  expenditure  responsibility  becomes  apparent. 
This  is  a  division  whereby  the  province  bears  the  cost  of  essentially  guaranteeing  that 
adequate  standards  of  education  will  prevail  everywhere  in  Ontario.  To  the  school 
board,  meanwhile,  is  left  the  critical  responsibility  of  determining  what  additional 
quality  of  education,  if  any,  shall  be  sought  over  and  above  provincial  standards. 

117.  We  approve  of  leaving  to  school  boards  the  important  role  of  determining 
marginal  school  expenditures  and  thereby  the  quality  of  education  that  shall  obtain 
locally.  This  critical  role  surely  befits  the  importance  of  local  autonomy  in  a  demo- 
cratic setting  and  makes  possible  the  diversity  and  experimentation  that  are  the 
key  to  educational  excellence.  At  the  same  time,  provincial  responsibility  for 
ensuring  that  adequate  standards  shall  prevail  in  all  localities  is  nowhere  more 
pressing  than  in  the  domain  of  education  whose  proper  provision  is  a  matter  of  the 
most  general,  indeed  national,  concern. 

118.  In  approving  the  present  division  of  spending  responsibilities  in  education, 
we  reject  such  item-by-item  divisions  as  are  sometimes  proposed.  To  make,  for 
example,  the  province  solely  responsible  for  construction  costs  while  leaving  to  the 
municipalities  the  bulk  of  operating  expenditure,  or  vice  versa,  would  be  an  act  of 
artificial  compartmentalization  which  ignored  the  extent  to  which  capital  costs 
affect  operating  costs.  Or,  to  take  another  example,  to  burden  the  provinces  with 
the  entire  cost  of  teachers'  salaries  would  fly  in  the  face  of  the  autonomy  of  school 
boards  in  appointing  teachers,  an  autonomy  that  not  only  enhances  local  importance 
but  safeguards  the  occupational  mobility  of  the  teaching  profession.    The  most 

54 


Chapter  2:  Paragraphs  115-122 

appropriate  division  of  spending  activities  in  education  is  surely  that  which  makes 
the  province  the  guarantor  of  educational  standards  and  the  local  school  board  the 
source  of  diversity.  It  is  this  division  that  best  reconciles  provincial  responsibility 
and  local  autonomy. 

THE  DIVISION  OF  REVENUE  SOURCES 

119.  The  local  share  of  educational  spending  is  met  entirely  through  the 
property  tax,  including  the  business  tax.  This  tax  is  levied  not  by  school  boards 
directly,  but  by  the  municipal  councils,  from  which  the  boards  requisition  their 
needs.  Two  questions  of  principle  consequently  arise  in  the  domain  of  educational 
finance.  The  first  involves  the  propriety  of  using  the  property  tax  to  pay  for  the 
local  share  of  school  expenditure.  The  second  arises  from  the  divorce  of  spending 
from  taxation  implicit  in  the  requisitioning  of  school  funds  from  municipalities. 

120.  The  propriety  of  using  the  property  tax  to  finance  the  local  share  of 
school  expenditure  has  become  a  matter  of  very  considerable  controversy.  There 
are  many  persons  who  contend  that  the  property  tax  bears  much  too  high  a  propor- 
tion of  the  cost  of  financing  local  education;  some  individuals,  including  certain 
witnesses  who  appeared  before  us  at  our  public  hearings,  even  support  the  extreme 
view  that  the  property  tax  should  have  no  place  whatever  in  educational  finance. 
The  stock  argument  advanced  in  support  of  this  contention  is  that  education  is 
not  a  service  whose  benefits  are  related  to  the  ownership  of  property  and  that  as 
long  as  the  property  tax  is  justified  on  the  basis  of  benefits  received,  it  cannot 
possibly  constitute  an  appropriate  levy  for  school  purposes. 

121.  While  we  take  a  sympathetic  view  of  the  financial  problems  that  have 
played  a  substantial  role  in  giving  currency  to  the  above  argument,  we  reject  it  as 
invalid.  Schools  do  confer  benefits  on  the  owners  of  property,  albeit  in  indirect 
fashion.  Neither  people  nor  business  firms  will  purchase  property  where  school 
facilities  are  not  provided.  In  an  age  where  consciousness  of  the  benefits  to  be 
derived  from  education  is  acute,  both  families  and  industrial  firms  will  tend  to 
consider  the  quality  of  a  community's  schools  before  deciding  on  location.  That 
municipalities  themselves  understand  the  practical  value  of  good  schools  is  abun- 
dantly evident  from  the  fact  that  their  own  promotional  literature  designed  to  en- 
courage further  settlement  and  industrial  expansion  seldom  fails  to  mention  the 
educational  advantages  which  the  community  offers.  The  fact  that  the  construction 
of  sewers  may  well  enhance  the  value  of  property  more  directly  than  schools  makes 
possible  a  legitimate  argument  to  the  effect  that  sewers  should  be  financed  entirely 
through  property  taxation  while  schools  should  rely  only  partly  on  this  tax.  But  it 
most  certainly  does  not  invalidate  the  use  of  the  property  tax  for  educational 
purposes. 

122.  Local  autonomy  demands  local  participation  in  school  finance.  The 
property  tax,  as  the  levy  most  amenable  to  local  administration  and  by  virtue  of  its 
directness  and  visibility,  serves  to  ensure  responsible  performance  in  the  field  of 
education.  If  school  costs  become  an  excessive  burden  on  property,  the  answer  is 
surely  to  be  found  in  increased  provincial  assistance  rather  than  total  removal  of 

55 


Intergovernmental  Fiscal  Relations 

the  property  tax  from  the  field  of  education.  The  latter  course  could  only  accentuate 
the  disease  that  had  brought  on  its  existence;  the  close  scrutiny  which  results  from 
financing  schools  through  the  property  tax  would  be  lost  and  local  cost  control 
irreparably  damaged. 

123.  The  issue  of  cost  control  brings  us  appropriately  to  what  we  consider  to 
be  the  second  major  problem  in  the  division  of  school  revenue  sources:  the  divorce 
of  spending  from  taxation  implicit  in  the  requisitioning  of  school  funds  from  muni- 
cipalities. This  practice  violates  the  principle  of  local  autonomy  by  enabUng  school 
boards  to  evade  direct  accountability  for  levels  of  taxation.  Important  elements  of 
cost  control  may  have  been  retained  in  that  no  municipal  council  transmits  school 
board  requisitions  to  the  taxpayer  without  identifying  them.  Nevertheless,  the 
practice  of  requisitioning  keeps  school  boards  one  critically  important  step  removed 
from  direct  confrontation  with  the  taxpayer.  It  is  our  considered  view  that  no 
principle  justifies  the  requisitioning  powers  of  school  boards.  One  way  to  end 
requisitioning,  of  course,  would  be  to  place  education  directly  under  the  municipal 
council,  as  in  the  United  Kingdom  and  the  Province  of  Alberta.  In  the  context  of 
the  present  Ontario  school  system,  the  principle  of  local  autonomy  at  least  demands 
that  school  boards  bill  the  taxpayer  directly  for  the  expenditures  they  undertake. 

THE  ROLE  OF  GRANTS 

124.  Implicit  in  our  views  about  the  place  of  the  property  tax  in  school  finance 
is  the  notion  that  education  is  a  function  in  which  provincial  grants  command  a 
leading  role.  This  is  so  for  two  reasons:  education  is  of  considerably  wider  than 
local  concern,  and  the  elusive  concept  of  equal  educational  opportunity  continues 
to  be  an  ideal  dearly  sought  after  by  all  democratic  states,  and  one  to  be  pursued 
by  all  feasible  means. 

125.  While  the  place  of  the  property  tax  in  school  finance  is  firmly  sanctioned 
by  considerations  of  local  autonomy  and  public  accountability,  we  believe  that  this 
tax  should  not  be  counted  upon  to  provide  the  major  part  of  the  costs  of  education. 
Education,  after  all,  is  a  function  whose  benefits  have  the  widest  possible  import. 
Its  implications  for  national  well-being  are  no  less,  and  perhaps  greater,  than  those 
of  defence  or  foreign  policy.  The  bulk  of  educational  expenditure  should  therefore 
be  financed  from  the  major  taxes  on  income,  consumption  and  wealth — as  indeed  it 
is  at  present,  if  universities  and  kindred  institutions  are  included  in  the  total  picture. 
We  are  of  the  opinion  that  this  rule  should  apply  specifically  to  elementary  and 
secondary  schools.    Provincial  responsibility  demands  no  less. 

126.  The  major  taxes  on  income,  consumption  and  wealth  can  contribute  to 
school  finance  only  through  the  medium  of  grants.  It  is  an  observation  of  the 
tritest  sort  to  remark  that  school  boards  are  hardly  in  a  position  to  levy  their  own 
income,  sales  and  inheritance  taxes.  Accordingly,  provincial  education  grants  rep- 
resent the  only  possible  application  to  local  schools  of  the  major  taxes  that  must 
properly  predominate  in  the  field  of  education. 

127.  If  grants  are  the  means  of  funneling  the  proceeds  of  major  taxes  to  the 
school  system,  they  have  no  less  important  a  task  in  the  realm  of  equalizing  educa- 

56 


Chapter  2:  Paragraphs  123-131 

tional  opportunity.  There  is  no  public  function  where  equalization  is  more  appro- 
priate than  education.  Here  is  an  instance  where  potential  conflicts  between 
notions  of  equity  and  economic  efficiency  are  minimal.  The  difference  between  an 
advanced  industrial  society  and  its  earlier  counterparts  is  that  today  we  can  no 
longer  afford  "mute,  inglorious  Miltons"  whose  condition  could  be  charged  to  a 
lack  of  educational  opportunity.  Moreover,  in  terms  of  political  values,  a  healthy 
democracy  demands  an  educated  citizenry,  for  without  one  it  will  not  long  survive. 

128.  There  is,  in  our  view,  only  one  point  beyond  which  financial  equalization 
should  not  be  carried.  This  is  the  point  at  which  the  dead  hand  of  uniformity 
would  descend  upon  the  school  system.  Diversity,  including  the  willingness  to 
provide  special  and  extraordinary  educational  services,  is  surely  the  key  to  an  out- 
standing school  system.  Here  is  where  the  imagination  and  motivation  born  of  local 
autonomy  return  prominently  into  the  picture. 

129.  Grants,  both  as  a  channel  of  income,  consumption  and  wealth  taxes  and 
as  the  financial  engine  of  equal  educational  opportunity,  must  predominate  in  the 
realm  of  educational  expenditure.  So-called  "foundation"  schemes  of  school 
finance,  which  we  shall  have  occasion  to  discuss  elsewhere  in  this  Report,  have 
proved  clearly  the  possibility  of  devising  grants  that  will  fulfil  both  roles.  There 
remains  the  question  of  whether  the  use  of  grants  for  stimulation  purposes  has  a 
place  on  the  educational  scene.  Stimulation  grants  can  of  course  be  made  on  behalf 
of  a  variety  of  services  ranging  from  textbooks  to  adult  education  classes. 

130.  In  considering  stimulation  grants,  it  is  well  to  remember  that  what  we 
have  called  the  principle  of  provincial  assistance  is  so  highly  developed  in  the  edu- 
cational domain  that  it  is  tantamount  to  provincial  supervision.  Vigilant  inspection, 
provincial  directives  affecting  curriculum,  lists  of  departmentally  approved  text- 
books, all  are  part  and  parcel  of  provincial-school  board  relations.  In  this  setting, 
the  existence  of  certain  stimulation  grants  that  attempt  to  encourage  school  boards 
to  carry  out  stated  programs  might  be  reconsidered  in  the  light  of  substituting 
therefor  an  appropriate  provincial  directive  with  a  corresponding  increase  in  the 
general  school  grants.  It  is  well  to  bear  in  mind  that  stimulation  grants  complicate 
an  already  intricate  grant  structure  and  that  they  have  the  uncertain  economic 
effects  described  earlier  no  less  among  school  boards  than  among  municipalities. 
They  should,  therefore,  be  instituted  only  in  a  spirit  of  the  utmost  restraint. 

THE  PROVINCE  AND  SCHOOL  BOUNDARIES 

131.  School  units,  like  their  municipal  counterparts,  can  be  too  small  to  dis- 
charge their  functions  in  an  efficient  and  accountable  manner.  The  decline  in  the 
number  of  one-room  rural  schools  and  recent  provincial  steps  in  reforming  rural 
school  boards  offer  abundant  testimony  to  this  fact.  We  wish  to  record  our  opinion, 
therefore,  that  the  viewpoint  which  we  developed  in  discussing  municipal  boundaries 
is  fully  applicable  to  school  boards.  Both  local  autonomy  and  provincial  responsi- 
bility demand  that  school  units  be  as  viable  as  circumstances  permit.  Not  only  the 
present  school  system,  but  its  further  development  into  vocational  and  post- 
secondary  phases,  is  critically  dependent  on  rational  and  responsive  organization. 

57 


Chapter 
3 


The  Committee's  Philosophy 
of  Government  Finance: 
Provincial  Fiscal  Policy 
and  Public  Borrowing 


1.  In  the  first  two  chapters  of  our  Report,  we  have  presented  our  broad  phi- 
losophy relating  to  the  desirable  characteristics  of  a  tax  system  and  of  intergovern- 
mental fiscal  relationships.  To  round  out  this  background,  we  shall  now  consider 
the  general  nature,  objectives  and  most  appropriate  use  of  provincial  fiscal  policy, 
a  concept  that  we  understand  to  include  all  decisions  affecting  the  aggregate  size 
and  composition  of  government  revenues  and  expenditures,  and  hence  to  the 
magnitude  of  the  government  surplus  or  deficit  in  any  given  period.  The  close 
relationship  between  fiscal  policy  decisions  and  cumulative  changes  in  the  public 
debt  is  therefore  readily  apparent. 

CHANGING  CONCEPTS  OF  FISCAL  POLICY 

2.  Until  the  Great  Depression  of  the  1930's,  the  most  appropriate  guide  to 
government  fiscal  policy  was  almost  universally  held  to  be  self-evident.  The  ideal 
objective  sought  by  all  governments — though  with  varying  degrees  of  success — was 
the  annually  balanced  budget.  The  appeal  of  this  particular  prescription  lay  partly 
in  its  simplicity,  partly  in  the  mistaken  behef  that  it  provided  an  effective  bulwark 
against  the  irresponsible  expenditure  of  public  funds,  and  partly  in  the  misconcep- 
tion that  hke  any  private  household  or  firm,  the  government  was  concerned  solely 

59 


Provincial  Fiscal  Policy  and  Public  Borrowing 

with  the  problem  of  financing  the  range  of  expenditures  to  which  it  found  itself 
committed  at  any  given  time.  In  short,  fiscal  performance  was  evaluated  in  the  light 
of  a  purely  financial  or  accounting  criterion,  applicable  to  successive  twelve-month 
periods  and  without  reference  to  periodic  fluctuations  in  the  general  level  of 
economic  activity. 

3.  The  cataclysmic  events  of  the  1930's  and  1940's,  ranging  from  severe  eco- 
nomic depression  to  the  acute  inflationary  pressures  of  war  time  and  the  ensuing 
economic  fluctuations  of  the  post-war  years,  have  all  served  to  reveal  and  clarify  the 
fundamental  inadequacies  of  the  balanced-budget  fiscal  philosophy.  Accordingly, 
modern  fiscal  theory  demonstrates  that  the  most  appropriate  cash  position  for  gov- 
ernment will  vary  with  changes  in  the  aggregate  level  of  activity  within  the  economy 
and  may  range  from  substantial  deficits  in  times  of  recession  to  substantial  surpluses 
in  times  of  inflationary  pressures.  When  actual  levels  of  production  are  below  the 
full-employment  potential,  the  stimulation  of  aggregate  demand  for  goods  and 
services  will  be  promoted  by  an  expansionist  fiscal  policy,  involving  the  creating  of 
deficits;  on  the  other  hand,  when  aggregate  demand  is  excessive  in  relation  to  avail- 
able productive  capacity,  it  will  be  curtailed  by  a  restrictive  fiscal  policy,  involving 
the  creating  of  surpluses.  These  varying  fiscal  effects  can  obviously  be  achieved, 
in  principle,  by  various  combinations  of  changes  in  taxation  and  expenditure,  the 
most  appropriate  combination  being  determined  in  the  light  of  the  prevailing 
economic  circumstances. 

4.  We  wish  to  make  clear  at  the  outset  that  fiscal  policy  should  not  be  regarded 
as  a  panacea  for  the  multiple  economic  ills  of  society.  In  so  far  as  it  is  directed 
to  minimizing  fluctuations  in  the  general  level  of  employment,  prices  and  production, 
its  success  will  depend  upon  its  effectiveness  in  creating  an  appropriate  level  of 
aggregate  demand  within  the  economy.  But  problems  of  unemployment  on  the 
one  hand,  or  of  inflation  on  the  other,  may  arise  from  a  multitude  of  causes  other 
than  a  general  deficiency  or  excess  of  demand  for  currently  produced  goods  and 
services.  To  be  specific,  unemployment  may  reflect  seasonal  influences  or  structural 
or  technological  changes,  and  government  must  utilize  an  appropriate  range  of 
weapons  if  these  problems  are  to  be  solved.  A  ready  example  is  provided  by  the 
continuing  efforts  of  the  Ontario  government  to  reduce  technological  unemploy- 
ment by  providing  continuously  expanding  programs  of  technical  and  vocational 
training  and  retraining.  The  use  of  fiscal  policy  is  properly  viewed  as  a  necessary 
instrument  in  the  attainment  of  society's  economic  objectives,  but  it  is  by  no  means 
sufficient  in  itself,  and  its  limitations  must  therefore  be  continuously  borne  in  mind. 

5.  Despite  the  growing  acceptance  of  the  proposition  that  taxation,  as  a  major 
component  of  government  fiscal  operations,  should  perform  not  only  a  financial  but 
a  much  broader  economic  function,  and  that  expenditure,  the  other  fiscal  compo- 
nent, should  likewise  be  varied  to  achieve  desirable  economic  ends,  support  for  the 
idea  of  an  annually  balanced  budget  dies  hard.  As  summarized  by  one  writer,  the 
".  .  .  deliberate  unbalancing  of  the  government  budget  in  order  to  balance  the 
economy  as  a  whole  conflicts  with  strongly  held  views  on  the  part  of  the  general 
public  with  respect  to  proper  budgetary  procedure.  The  average  citizen  still  believes 

60 


I 


Chapter    3:    Paragraphs    3-8 

— and  here  his  view  is  shared  by  much  of  the  daily  press — that  a  government  should 
attempt  to  maintain  a  balance  between  its  revenues  and  its  expenditures."^ 

6.  If  pursued  rigidly  by  all  levels  of  government,  regardless  of  changes  in 
underlying  economic  conditions,  the  policy  of  the  annually  balanced  budget  would 
bring  higher  taxes  and  decreased  government  expenditures  in  recession,  lower  taxes 
and  increased  expenditures  in  inflation,  and  accordingly  could  lead  only  to  the 
aggravation  of  economic  instability  and  eventually  to  economic  disruption.  Despite 
such  consequences,  the  balanced-budget  tradition  has  remained  strong,  even  at  the 
highest  levels  of  government,  and  for  much  of  the  post-war  period  Canadian  fiscal 
policy  was  significantly  impaired  by  the  view,  apparently  shared  by  successive 
ministers  of  finance,  that  deficits  are  a  curse  and  only  to  be  suffered  most  unwill- 
ingly. One  authority  has  observed  that  "...  even  political  leaders  who  understand 
and  accept  modern  fiscal  theory  find  themselves  very  much  on  the  defensive  when 
the  budget  is  in  deficit. "^ 

7.  It  is  nevertheless  true  that  since  the  end  of  World  War  II,  many  national 
governments,  including  that  of  Canada,  have  assumed  prime  responsibility  for 
promoting  a  continuously  high  level  of  economic  activity.  The  effective  pursuit 
of  this  objective  requires  the  use  of  their  fiscal  powers  to  achieve  an  appropriate 
level  of  aggregate  demand  for  the  goods  and  services  that  their  economies  are 
capable  of  producing.  This  objective  is  obviously  well  beyond  the  responsibility  and 
the  ability  of  private  economic  units.  By  generating  a  cash  surplus  in  any  period, 
the  government  effects  a  net  withdrawal  of  funds  from  the  private  sector  of  the 
economy  and  thereby  tends  to  ease  inflationary  pressures.  By  generating  a  deficit, 
the  resulting  net  addition  to  private  funds  can  stimulate  demand  and  contribute 
to  the  maintenance  of  the  desired  high  level  of  economic  activity. 

8.  The  government  of  Canada  cannot  be  said  to  have  been  either  an  enthusiastic 
or  a  consistent  practitioner  of  counter-cyclical  fiscal  policy  during  the  two  decades 
since  World  War  II.  Yet  in  the  immediate  post-war  years,  its  fiscal  policies  reflected 
its  early  explicit  recognition  and  advocacy  of  the  need  to  use  the  budget  as  a  crucial 
economic  instrument.  Speaking  in  1948,  the  Minister  of  Finance  noted  that 
".  .  .  if  our  budget  problem  were  simply  and  solely  to  find  enough  revenue  this 
year  to  meet  our  expenditures  defined  in  the  narrow  accounting  sense,  we  could 
afford  to  reduce  taxes  by  a  substantial  amount.  But  that  is  not  our  budget  problem, 
and  if  we  approached  our  affairs  in  such  a  short-sighted  manner,  we  would  betray 
our  responsibility.  ...  I  believe  that  all  parties  in  this  parliament  and  most  Cana- 
dians share  the  view  that  the  national  budget  is  no  longer  merely  a  matter  of  the 
government  accounts  that  should  be  balanced  every  twelve  months  on  some  finan- 
cial rule  of  thumb.  We  view  the  national  budget  now  as  an  integral  part  of  the 
nation's  business,  influenced  by  and  having  an  influence  upon  the  state  of  employ- 
ment, income  and  prices.  .  .  ."^ 

'See  Clarence  L.  Barber,  Provincial  Fiscal  Policy,  Toronto:  Queen's  Printer,  1967,  p.  1. 
See  also  Chapter  1  of  this  work  for  a  discussion  of  the  current  theory  of  fiscal  policy. 
^See  Otto  Eckstein,  Public  Finance,  Englewood  Cliffs:  Prentice-Hall,  Inc.,  1964,  p.  95. 
'Canada,  Minister  of  Finance,  Budget  Speech,  May  18,   1948,  pp.  9-10. 

61 


Provincial  Fiscal  Policy  and  Public  Borrowing 

9.  In  Canada  as  elsewhere,  the  use  of  fiscal  policy  as  an  instrument  of  economic 
stabilization  has  been  regarded  as  the  sole  responsibihty  of  the  central  government. 
There  is  no  reliable  evidence  that  any  province  has  consciously  embodied  stability 
objectives  as  a  determinant  of  its  fiscal  operations  at  any  time  since  the  end  of 
World  War  II.  Provincial  governments  have  generally  regarded  as  both  unnecessary 
and  impracticable  the  deliberate  use  of  their  own  taxing  and  spending  powers  to 
minimize  fluctuations  in  employment,  production  and  the  general  price  level.  For 
reasons  that  we  shall  proceed  to  develop,  it  is  our  view  that  such  a  position  is  no 
longer  tenable  if  national  and  provincial  economic  objectives  are  to  be  pursued 
most  effectively.  In  this  connection,  we  are  encouraged  by  some  very  recent  state- 
ments of  policy  by  the  Provincial  Treasurer  of  Ontario.  These  appear  to  imply 
the  gradual  disappearance  of  an  era  in  which  the  growing  provincial  debt  has  been 
viewed  in  purely  negative  terms,  as  an  inevitable  and  unpleasant  fact  of  life  to  be 
reluctantly  tolerated.  In  particular,  the  Minister  has  spoken  of  the  warranted  size 
of  a  "planned"  deficit  in  relation  to  prevailing  economic  and  fiscal  conditions 
within  the  province.* 

10.  We  note  in  our  next  chapter  that  during  the  past  quarter-century,  the  trend 
in  Ontario's  provincial  debt  has  been  persistently  upward  and  that  its  growth 
presents  no  definable  cyclical  pattern,  such  as  might  be  expected  if  counter-cyclical 
fiscal  policy  had  been  adopted.  The  debt  has  grown  in  both  prosperity  and  depres- 
sion, a  reflection  of  the  consistent  policy  of  the  government  of  Ontario  to  finance 
its  entire  ordinary  expenditures  and  some  part  of  its  capital  expenditures  from 
revenues,  the  remainder  of  its  capital  program  being  financed  by  borrowing.  This 
particular  pattern  of  finance  clearly  reflects  the  long-held  "orthodox"  view  that  at 
least  in  its  "ordinary"  operations,  the  government  must  at  all  times  balance  its 
accounts.  The  terms  of  borrowing,  and  particularly  the  maturity  of  the  Province's 
debt,  have  been  customarily  determined  by  market  conditions  and  not  by  the  life- 
time of  the  assets  acquired.  The  practical  result  of  this  pattern  of  finance  has  been 
that  during  the  past  decade,  the  annual  deficit  of  the  government  of  Ontario  has 
averaged  approximately  1  per  cent  of  provincial  personal  income,  a  ratio  that  is 
typical  of  the  provincial  situation  in  Canada.^ 

INSTRUMENTS  OF  ECONOMIC  POLICY 

1 1 .  Before  providing  a  general  assessment  of  the  burden  of  Ontario's  present 
debt  and  of  its  prospective  development  to  1974-75,  we  wish  to  develop  further 
our  views  concerning  the  potential  contribution  of  a  positive  provincial  fiscal  policy 
to  the  economic  well-being  both  of  Ontario  and  of  the  nation.  At  the  level  of 
national  governments,  it  is  well  recognized  that  the  two  broadest  or  most  general 
instruments  available  for  promoting  the  major  economic  objectives  of  stability  and 
growth  are  fiscal  policy  and  monetary  policy.  Monetary  policy  encompasses  all 
government  decisions  designed  to  influence  the  general  availability  and  cost  of  credit 
within  the  economy,  a  range  of  activities  that  constitutes  the  major  function  of  the 
central  bank.  The  immediate  aim  of  monetary  policy  is  to  induce  appropriate  vari- 


*See,  for  example,  Ontario  Budget  Speech,  February  9,  1966. 
"See  Barber,  Provincial  Fiscal  Policy,  pp.  46-7. 

62 


Chapter   3:    Paragraphs   9-14 

ations  in  the  state  of  the  economy's  over-all  liquidity  and  hence  to  influence  the 
rate  of  money  expenditure  on  goods  and  services.  The  close  interrelationship 
between  monetary  and  fiscal  policies  will  therefore  be  readily  apparent. 

12.  Monetary  and  fiscal  instruments  are  "general"  in  the  sense  that  their  effects 
pervade  the  entire  economy.  They  may  therefore  be  contrasted  with  more  selective 
measures  designed  to  improve  productivity  in  particular  sectors  of  the  economy, 
such  as  those  directed  to  the  improvement  of  the  education  and  technical  skills  of 
the  labour  force,  the  stimulation  of  scientific  research  and  development,  changes  in 
the  market  structure  of  industry,  and  regional  resource  development.  It  is  clear 
that  the  economic  objectives  of  stability  and  growth  are  closely  interrelated,  in  that 
success  in  achieving  stability  in  the  short  run  will  at  the  same  time  further  the 
longer-term  objective  of  economic  growth.  Elsewhere  in  our  Report  we  stress  the 
crucial  importance  of  a  sound  tax  structure  in  the  attainment  of  this  latter  objective. 
The  particular  point  we  wish  to  emphasize  here  is  that  while  both  general  and 
selective  measures  of  economic  policy  are  relevant  to  promoting  economic  growth, 
the  battle  to  minimize  short-run  cyclical  instability  must  be  fought  mainly  with 
the  general  weapons  of  monetary  and  fiscal  pohcy. 

13.  Within  the  Canadian  federation,  monetary  policy  has  always  been  regarded 
as  the  sole  prerogative  of  the  central  government,  for  if  the  concept  of  a  "nation" 
is  to  be  at  all  meaningful,  the  existence  of  a  common  monetary  policy  is  surely 
one  of  its  basic  economic  prerequisites.  Because  this  policy  must  at  any  time  be 
based  on  a  consensus  of  the  national  economic  interest,  it  will  not  necessarily  serve 
all  regional  interests  equally  well,  but  in  the  context  of  a  capital  market  that  is  not 
merely  national  but  international  in  scope,  the  notion  of  separate  regional  monetary 
policies  formulated  and  administered  by  a  central  bank  must  be  judged  completely 
impracticable.  As  an  economic  instrument,  monetary  policy  appears  capable  of 
providing  a  more  efTective  contribution  to  long-run  growth  than  to  short-term 
stability.  This  circumstance  arises  not  only  from  undesirably  long  lags  inherent  in 
the  use  of  monetary  policy — a  weakness  shared  in  some  degree  by  fiscal  measures 
— but  from  external  balance-of-payments  pressures  and  other  constraints  which 
have  progressively  impeded  the  orienting  of  Canada's  monetary  policy  primarily  to 
domestic  economic  objectives.  As  an  example  of  this  kind  of  difficulty,  it  may 
simply  be  impossible,  given  the  great  sensitivity  of  short-term  capital  to  international 
interest-rate  differentials,  to  lower  Canadian  interest  rates  to  the  levels  most  appro- 
priate for  stimulating  the  economy  when  substantial  unemployment  prevails. 
Because  a  truly  independent  national  monetary  policy  is  not  realistic,  fiscal  policy 
has  become  the  Canadian  government's  major  instrument  of  economic  stabilization. 

CONFLICTS  AMONG  ECONOMIC  OBJECTIVES 

14.  In  Chapter  1,  we  included  stability  and  growth  among  the  major  economic 
objectives  of  society  and  we  noted  that  government  fiscal  policy  now  provides  an 
important  range  of  instruments  to  be  directed  to  the  pursuit  of  these  objectives. 
In  placing  major  emphasis  on  the  attainment  of  stability  (of  employment,  produc- 
tion and  price  levels)  in  the  following  discussion,  we  in  no  way  wish  to  minimize 
the  crucial  importance  of  generating  sustained  economic  growth  within  this  province 

63 


Provincial  Fiscal  Policy  and  Public  Borrowing 

and  the  nation.  On  the  contrary,  we  recognize  the  greatest  need  for  providing  a 
tax  system  that  will  lend  maximum  encouragement  to  continuously  rising  levels  of 
productivity  within  the  Canadian  economy.  Within  our  own  terms  of  reference,  we 
have  sought  to  advance  recommendations  that  we  think  will  contribute  to  this 
result.  Our  view  has  been  that  the  productive  potential  of  the  Ontario  economy 
is  based  upon  the  quantity  and  quality  of  its  available  labour  and  marginal  skills 
and  capital  equipment,  and  upon  the  technology  at  hand  for  embodiment  in  the 
productive  process.  A  major  contribution  of  tax  policy  to  rising  productivity  and 
long-run  economic  growth  therefore  lies  in  its  encouragement  of  a  growing  stock  of 
human  resources  with  increasingly  diverse  skills  and  in  a  comparable  continuing 
flow  of  investment  into  technologically  advanced  forms  of  capital  equipment. 
Equally  important  to  the  attainment  of  satisfactory  growth  is  the  formulation  of  tax 
measures  that  encourage  the  employment  of  these  productive  resources  in  their 
most  efficient  uses. 

15.  Our  review  of  the  past  performance  of  the  Ontario  economy  nevertheless 
leads  us  to  the  conclusion  that  perhaps  the  most  important  single  contribution  which 
tax  policy  may  contribute  to  the  economic  growth  of  the  province  lies  in  its  modera- 
tion of  undesirable  short-term  fluctuations  in  employment,  production  and  price 
levels — in  other  words,  in  its  contribution  to  economic  stability.  In  this  context, 
the  importance  of  maintaining  continuous  high  levels  of  employment  and  production 
is  perhaps  too  obvious  to  require  elaboration,  but  the  objective  of  a  stable  general 
price  level  is  likewise  crucial,  and  for  two  reasons.  When  significant  changes  occur 
in  the  general  price  level,  the  prices  of  particular  goods  and  services  will  inevitably 
change  at  varying  rates,  thereby  introducing  arbitrary  changes  in  the  distribution  of 
income  among  various  groups  within  the  economy.  These  distortions  of  cost-price- 
selling-price  relationships  inevitably  create  inequities,  lessen  the  efliciency  of  the 
productive  process  and  thereby  impede  the  attainment  of  economic  objectives.  A 
second  aspect  of  the  problem  is  that  even  if  every  individual  price  rose  (or  declined) 
at  the  same  rate,  thereby  avoiding  the  distortions  we  have  just  indicated,  serious 
difficulties  would  still  arise  as  between  lenders  and  borrowers  within  the  economy, 
the  dollars  repaid  being  worth  less  (or  more),  in  real  terms,  than  the  dollars 
borrowed.  Here  the  resulting  redistribution  of  real  wealth  again  creates  inequities 
and  lessens  the  efficiency  of  the  economic  process. 

16.  We  must  nevertheless  recognize  that  at  any  given  time  in  Canada,  as  else- 
where, the  objectives  of  fuller  employment,  greater  price-level  stability  and  more 
rapid  economic  growth  may  conflict  with  one  another,  in  that  it  may  not  be  possible 
for  all  to  be  achieved  simultaneously.  Difficult  choices  must  therefore  be  made,  in 
the  light  of  the  "trade-offs"  that  appear  possible  among  various  objectives.  It  may 
be  decided,  for  example,  that  a  4  per  cent  average  annual  rate  of  unemployment 
will  be  an  acceptable  object  of  national  policy  because  the  attainment  of  any  lower 
rate  would  involve  too  high  a  price  in  terms  of  additional  inflation.  If  this  is  so, 
then  4  per  cent  unemployment  becomes  the  working  interpretation  of  "full  employ- 
ment" and  the  government's  appropriate  fiscal  position  will  be  that  which  con- 
tributes to  the  level  of  aggregate  demand  appropriate  to  sustaining  the  required 

64 


Chapter  3:  Paragraphs  15-19 

employment  level.  Viewed  in  this  general  context,  the  continuing  goal  of  the  totality 
of  government  economic  policy  will  be  to  improve  the  trade-off  terms — i.e.,  to 
lessen  the  costs  of  pursuing  particular  objectives  more  fully,  or  to  put  it  more 
directly,  to  lessen  the  degree  of  conflict  among  competing  economic  objectives. 

17.  Having  adopted  some  practical  quantitative  definition  of  full  employment, 
the  government  must  then  attempt  the  difficult  task  of  projecting  the  potential  gross 
national  product  of  the  economy  under  these  full-employment  conditions,  if  appro- 
priate counter-cyclical  fiscal  policy  is  to  be  devised.  Given  the  current  structure 
and  rates  of  taxation  and  given  the  current  structure  of  its  spending  programs,  the 
government  will  then  be  able  to  estimate  the  total  revenues  and  expenditures  that 
these  would  produce,  at  the  potential  full-employment  level  of  gross  national 
product.  The  resulting  relationship  is  known  as  the  government's  full-employment 
surplus  or  deficit. 

THE  NEED  FOR  "DISCRETIONARY"  FISCAL  POLICY 

18.  From  the  point  of  view  of  economic  stabilization,  government  revenues 
and  expenditures  should  approximate  a  balance  only  when  the  nation's  rate  of  out- 
put (gross  national  product)  reflects  a  condition  of  full  employment.  It  therefore 
follows  that  in  periods  of  economic  recession,  the  fiscal  system  should  produce 
deficits,  while  in  periods  of  strong  inflationary  pressures  it  should  produce  surpluses. 
Where  the  effect  of  current  tax  and  expenditure  programs  is  to  produce  a  balance 
in  the  government's  accounts  before  the  full-employment  level  of  gross  national 
product  has  been  achieved  (and  where  a  potential  surplus  at  full  employment  is 
therefore  indicated),  this  potential  surplus  constitutes  what  has  become  known  as 
the  "fiscal  drag".  The  term  is  self-explanatory,  in  that  the  government's  net  with- 
drawal of  funds  from  the  stream  of  private  expenditures,  in  an  economy  that  has 
not  yet  attained  the  desired  level  of  full  employment,  renders  unattainable  the 
level  of  aggregate  demand  required  to  reach  this  employment  and  production 
objective. 

19.  It  is  true  that  government  fiscal  operations  embody  a  limited  degree  of 
"built-in"  flexibility  and  thereby  provide  some  tendencies  to  stabilization  through 
the  automatic  changes  that  occur  both  in  revenues  and  expenditures  as  the  general 
level  of  economic  activity  changes.  Most  striking  on  the  revenue  side  are  the 
automatic  variations  in  the  personal  income  tax  receipts,  a  reflection  of  the  gradu- 
ated rate  structure  of  the  tax.  On  the  expenditure  side  of  the  government's  fiscal 
operations,  the  built-in  stabilizing  effects  are  best  displayed  by  the  changing  levels 
of  unemployment  insurance  benefits  and  various  welfare  payments.  The  operation 
of  fiscal  drag  nevertheless  emphasizes  the  need  for  placing  major  reliance  upon 
discretionary  changes  in  revenue  and  expenditure  programs.  In  a  growing  economy, 
with  these  programs  remaining  unchanged — i.e.,  with  no  discretionary  or  deliberate 
fiscal  action — the  effect  of  a  continuously  rising  level  of  production  in  conjunction 
with  a  progressive  tax  structure  will  be  that  tax  revenues  represent  a  larger  and 
larger  proportion  of  national  income,  and  that  a  larger  and  larger  full-employment 
surplus  (government  revenues  rising  relative  to  expenditures)  will  be  generated. 
This  increasingly  burdensome  fiscal  drag  would  restrain  the  rate  of  economic 

65 


Provincial  Fiscal  Policy  and  Public  Borrowing 

growth  and,  as  indicated,  prevent  the  attainment  of  full  employment  at  any  given 
time.  What  is  required,  therefore,  is  the  continuous  exercise  of  fiscal  discretion  in 
an  effort  to  balance  government  revenues  and  expenditures  only  at  the  continuously 
rising  levels  of  gross  national  product  that  full  employment  makes  possible  in  a 
growing  economy.  In  so  far  as  discretionary  action  is  embodied  in  tax  policy,  there 
are  two  very  important  criteria  of  what  particular  taxes  should  be  changed.  These 
are  the  promptness  and  the  reliability  with  which  any  rate  changes  will  transmit  their 
effects  to  the  economy.  To  retain  the  greatest  degree  of  tax  equity,  the  broad  lines 
of  the  stabilization  program  should  have  been  formulated  and  generally  agreed 
upon  in  advance  of  its  utilization. 

20.  Because  Canadian  monetary  policy  has  in  recent  years  been  subjected  to 
increasingly  severe  constraints,  it  appears  that  the  main  attack  on  economic 
instability  must  in  the  foreseeable  future  be  launched  with  fiscal  weapons.  In  our 
view,  the  national  interest  requires  that  primary  responsibility  in  this  area  remain 
with  the  central  government,  for  which  purpose  it  must  of  course  retain  an 
adequate  fiscal  arsenal.  But  unlike  the  exercise  of  monetary  policy,  the  fiscal 
operations  of  the  provinces  and  their  municipalities  represent  a  strategic  and 
increasingly  powerful  economic  influence  within  Canada.  Their  combined  annual 
expenditures  now  exceed  those  of  the  federal  government,  and  a  Canadian  Minister 
of  Finance  has  noted  that  ".  .  .  changes  in  provincial  revenues  and  expenditures,  and 
in  their  budgetary  balance,  have  a  major  effect  upon  growth  and  stability  in  the 
Canadian  economy.  It  follows  too  that  the  timing  of  their  expenditure  measures 
can  be  such  as  to  contribute  to  a  steady  growth  of  production  and  jobs,  or  the 
reverse. "° 

INCREASING  IMPORTANCE  OF  PROVINCIAL  AND  MUNICIPAL  FINANCE 

21.  Since  the  end  of  World  War  II,  the  aggregate  revenues  and  expenditures 
of  all  levels  of  government  within  Canada  have  grown  rapidly,  both  in  absolute 
terms  and  in  relation  to  the  financial  transactions  of  the  private  sector  of  the 
economy.  Some  indication  of  the  importance  of  the  financial  activities  of  all 
governments  in  Canada  is  provided  by  the  fact  that  in  1964,  their  collective  expendi- 
tures on  goods  and  services  amounted  to  $8.6  billion,  of  which  the  federal  govern- 
ment accounted  for  $3.0  billion  and  provincial  and  municipal  governments 
$5.6  billion.  This  aggregate  represented  some  18  per  cent  of  Canadian  gross 
national  product.  In  addition,  their  transfer  payments  to  the  private  sector — i.e., 
excluding  intergovernmental  transfers — approximated  $6.0  billion,  of  which  the 
federal  government  disbursed  $3.5  billion  and  provincial  and  municipal  govern- 
ments $2.5  billion.  The  resulting  total  government  expenditure  of  $14.6  billion 
amounted  to  some  3 1  per  cent  of  gross  national  product.  It  is  particularly  interest- 
ing to  note  that  while  the  federal  share  of  this  total,  $6.5  billion,  reflects  a  growth 
of  56  per  cent  during  the  past  decade,  the  provincial-municipal  share,  $8.1  billion, 
has  grown  by  more  than  200  per  cent  during  the  same  period. 

22.  During  1964,  the  total  revenues  of  the  federal  government  approximated 
$8.1  billion,  of  which  some  $1.3  billion  was  transferred  to  provincial  and  municipal 


'See  Minister  of  Finance,  Budget  Speech,  April  26,  1965,  p.  8. 

66 


Chapter  3:  Paragraphs  20-25 

authorities.  Coupled  with  its  foregoing  transfers  to  the  private  sector  and  with  its 
expenditures  on  goods  and  services,  the  federal  government  is  therefore  seen  to 
have  generated  a  modest  surplus  of  $0.3  billion.  Total  combined  provincial- 
municipal  revenues,  excluding  the  indicated  transfer  payments  from  the  federal 
government,  amounted  to  $7.7  billion.  Their  combined  deficit,  similarly  measured 
on  a  national-accounts  basis,  therefore  approximated  $0.3  billion,  in  reality  exceed- 
ing slightly  the  federal  government  surplus.  The  effect  of  the  intergovernmental 
transfers  was  to  reduce  the  federal  government's  share  of  combined  revenues  from 
56  to  47  per  cent  and  conversely  to  increase  the  provincial-municipal  share  from 
44  to  53  per  cent.  It  is  interesting  to  note  that  provincial  governments  transfer  to 
local  authorities  an  aggregate  amount  almost  equal  to  that  which  they  receive 
from  the  federal  government. 

NEED  FOR  INTERGOVERNMENTAL  FISCAL  CO-ORDINATION 

23.  Given  the  magnitude  of  these  financial  transactions  in  the  public  sector 
of  the  Canadian  economy,  it  may  be  readily  appreciated  that  government  fiscal 
policies — i.e.,  policies  relating  to  the  levels,  composition  and  timing  of  public 
revenues  and  expenditures — represent  a  powerful  and  inescapable  influence  on  the 
general  level  of  economic  activity  within  this  country.  If  used  effectively  as  one 
component  of  government  economic  policy,  these  fiscal  instruments  can  contribute 
greatly  to  the  attainment  of  the  nation's  economic  objectives,  whereas  if  they  are 
not  so  used  the  objectives  may  be  impossible  of  attainment. 

24.  In  this  connection,  it  should  be  noted  that  the  events  of  recent  years  have 
undermined  the  fiscal  powers  of  the  federal  government,  in  respect  of  both  its 
revenues  and  its  expenditures.  With  regard  to  revenues,  the  provinces  once  again 
legislate  their  own  rates  of  direct  taxation  (personal  and  corporate  income  taxes). 
In  addition,  the  development  of  the  technique  of  federal  tax  abatement  has  facili- 
tated the  greater  use  of  these  particular  tax  fields  by  the  provinces,  leaving  the 
federal  government  with  a  correspondingly  reduced  share  of  these  fields.  Both  of 
these  developments  have  substantially  lessened  federal  control  over  what  are 
generally  recognized  as  the  most  effective  instruments  of  economic  stabilization.  It 
may  well  be  that  the  most  important  economic  issue  concerning  the  appropriate 
limits  to  federal-provincial  fiscal  arrangements  and  the  tax  areas  to  which  they 
might  be  extended  hinges  upon  the  minimum  requirements  for  the  retention  of 
effective  fiscal  control  by  the  federal  government.  On  the  expenditure  side  it  is 
likewise  quite  clear  not  only  that  provincial-municipal  outlays  substantially  exceed 
those  of  the  government  of  Canada  but  that  their  relative  importance  will  continue 
to  grow.  Moreover,  those  particular  areas  of  expenditure  that  appear  to  be  most 
adaptable  to  cyclical  variation — i.e.,  welfare,  roads  and  housing — represent  areas 
either  of  provincial  or  of  constitutionally  shared  jurisdiction,  where  intergovern- 
mental co-operation  therefore  becomes  essential  for  most  effective  action. 

25.  The  continuing  trend  toward  fiscal  decentralization  within  the  Canadian 
federation  is  a  process  that  may  be  seen,  in  historical  perspective,  as  a  reaction  to 
the  abnormal  centralization  of  economic  power  that  occurred  during  World  War  II 

67 


Provincial  Fiscal  Policy  and  Public  Borrowing 

and  to  sharply  and  continuously  rising  expenditures  in  areas  constitutionally  allo- 
cated to  the  provinces.  Such  a  trend  points  up  the  growing  unreality  of  the  view 
that  fiscal  stabilization  policy  should  remain  the  exclusive  responsibility  of  the 
federal  government.  The  effective  use  of  such  policy  implies  not  merely  the  need 
to  avoid  fiscal  measures  operating  at  cross-purposes  but,  more  positively,  that 
provincial  action  in  this  area  be  formulated  with  a  conscious  recognition  of  its 
stabilizing  potential.  This  is  a  particularly  important  consideration  for  those 
provinces  whose  aggregate  revenues  and  expenditures  are  large  enough  to  exert 
significant  effects  upon  the  Canadian  economy. 

26.  The  economic  history  of  Canada  provides  repeated  demonstrations  of  the 
fact  that  at  any  given  time,  the  general  level  of  economic  activity  may  vary 
substantially  from  one  province  to  another.  It  follows  that  broad  stabilization 
policies  originated  by  the  federal  government  will  not  be  likely  to  cope  with 
regional  problems  with  equal  effectiveness  and  that  co-operative  provincial  fiscal 
measures  can  sharpen  the  attack  in  particular  regions.  One  might  further  hope 
that  the  assurance  of  such  co-operation  from  the  provinces  would  encourage  the 
federal  government  to  promote  its  own  stabilization  programs  on  a  scale  not 
heretofore  thought  to  be  practicable. 

27.  It  is  therefore  our  firm  view  that  the  Province  of  Ontario  should  recognize 
its  own  substantial  responsibility  for  promoting  economic  stabihzation  and  should 
therefore  undertake  to  formulate  and  implement  a  continuing  policy  of  counter- 
cyclical financing.  Such  a  policy  is  required  in  the  interest  of  both  the  provincial 
and  the  national  economy. 

28.  In  the  course  of  our  studies  in  this  important  area  of  economic  policy, 
we  have  been  encouraged  to  learn  that  a  number  of  provinces  have  already  com- 
mitted themselves  to  the  principle,  if  not  yet  the  practice,  of  counter-cyclical 
finance.  Discussion  with  provincial  officials  has  further  suggested  a  general  willing- 
ness on  the  part  of  the  provinces  to  complement  federal  policies  designed  to  cope 
with  the  inequities  and  economic  inefficiencies  of  these  cyclical  fluctuations.  The 
obstacle  to  the  initiation  of  effective  provincial  fiscal  action  has  frequently  been 
explained  as  lying  not  in  any  failure  to  recognize  its  desirability  but  in  the  financial 
difficulties  involved.  With  reference  to  the  Province  of  Ontario,  we  therefore 
now  wish  to  shift  our  discussion  from  the  desirability  of  counter-cyclical  financing 
to  the  question  of  its  practicability,  noting  at  the  outset  that  "practicability" 
involves  both  financial  and  technical  requirements. 

FEASIBILITY  OF  PROVINCIAL  COUNTER-CYCLICAL  FISCAL  POLICY 

29.  The  possible  limitations  on  the  ability  of  Ontario  to  adopt  counter-cyclical 
financing  have  been  discussed  at  some  length  in  a  study  sponsored  and  published  by 
this  Committee,'^  and  because  we  find  ourselves  in  broad  agreement  with  its 
findings,  we  wish  to  emphasize  several  aspects  of  that  discussion.  It  is  frequently 
suggested  that  in  contrast  to  the  federal  government,  the  Province's  lack  of  control 
over  monetary  poUcy  will  seriously  limit  its  ability  to  engage  in  counter-cyclical 


'See  Barber,  Provincial  Fiscal  Policy. 

68 


Chapter  3:  Paragraphs  26-32 

financing.  It  is  of  course  true  that  when  undertaking  a  program  of  deficit  financ- 
ing to  combat  recession,  the  federal  government  will  look  to  the  Bank  of  Canada 
as  the  major  buyer  of  its  securities  and  as  a  source  of  support  for  the  bond  market. 
To  the  extent,  however,  that  such  a  policy  of  monetary  expansion  is  constrained  by 
external  balance-of-payments  considerations  (and  such  monetary  constraints  are 
likely  to  be  substantial  under  our  present  system  of  fixed  exchange  rates  to  which 
we  appear  to  be  committed  for  the  foreseeable  future)  the  distinctive  advantage 
accruing  to  the  federal  government  is  correspondingly  diminished. 

30.  On  the  other  hand,  if  the  Bank  of  Canada  succeeds  in  estabUshing  the 
easy-money,  low-interest-rate  conditions  appropriate  to  domestic  recession,  its 
beneficial  effects  will  certainly  accrue  to  provincial  goverimients.  Given  the 
international  mobility  of  capital  characteristic  of  the  Canadian  economy,  monetary 
pohcy  will  be  the  relatively  more  effective  stabilization  instrument  where  flexible 
exchange  rates  prevail  and  fiscal  policy  relatively  more  effective  under  a  regime  of 
fixed  exchange  rates,  as  at  present. 

31.  It  will  readily  be  conceded  that  the  effective  provincial  operation  of 
counter-cyclical  fiscal  policy  requires  that  appropriate  monetary  conditions  be 
provided  by  the  central  authorities.  We  think  that  in  the  Canadian  economy  such 
conditions  generally  will  be  provided  in  any  given  period,  barring  the  unusual 
circumstance  in  which  regional  cycUcal  fluctuations  vary  not  merely  in  degree  but 
in  their  absolute  direction.  Were  this  situation  to  arise,  it  would  obviously  be 
financially  imprudent,  for  example,  for  the  Province  of  Ontario  or  any  other 
province  to  contemplate  incurring  the  size  of  deficit,  with  the  accompanying 
expansion  of  its  debt,  likely  to  be  effective  in  coping  with  provincial  economic 
recession,  at  the  same  time  as  the  federal  government  pursued  a  policy  of  tighter 
and  dearer  money  to  curb  inflation  that  might  be  generally  characteristic  of  the 
nation's  economy. 

32.  Because  the  stabilizing  effects  of  fiscal  policy  are  related  to  its  impact 
upon  the  aggregate  demand  for  current  production,  its  initial  objective  is  to  alter 
the  level  of  disposable  income  in  the  private  sector  of  the  economy.  The  actual 
manner  of  disposition  of  this  income  then  becomes  crucially  important.  If,  for 
example,  the  effect  of  counter-cyclical  fiscal  policy  during  recession  has  been  to 
increase  private  disposable  income,  the  stimulating  effects  upon  the  economy  may 
be  disappointingly  small.  This  may  be  so  if  much  of  this  additional  income  is 
saved  rather  than  spent,  or  if  spent,  is  used  to  purchase  goods  produced  elsewhere 
rather  than  within  the  domestic  economy.  Such  savings  or  expenditures  on  "out- 
side" goods  and  services  are  commonly  known  as  leakages  from  the  flow  of 
domestic  expenditures.  It  will  be  obvious  that  the  larger  the  geographic  area  (to 
take  just  one  variable)  in  which  stabilization  policy  is  practised,  the  smaller  the 
leakages  are  likely  to  be.  Thus,  for  the  Canadian  economy  as  a  whole,  the  leak- 
ages from  additional  income,  apart  from  additions  to  saving,  are  represented  by 
any  increased  expenditures  directed  to  imports  from  abroad  rather  than  to 
domestic  production.  For  the  Ontario  economy,  leakages  encompass  the  spending 
of  its  residents  not  only  outside  Canada  but   anywhere   outside   the   province. 

69 


Provincial  Fiscal  Policy  and  Public  Borrowing 

For  a  municipal  economy,  the  leakages  from  rising  incomes  are  likely  to  be  very 
great  indeed. 

33.  It  is  clear  that  of  all  Canadian  provinces,  Ontario  would  suffer  least  from 
income  leakages  associated  with  its  counter-cyclical  fiscal  operations.  The  fact 
that  the  estimated  magnitude  of  such  leakages  is  less  than  those  of  many  indepen- 
dent nations  reflects  both  the  size  and  diversification  of  her  economy.  There  is  no 
doubt  that  the  Ontario  economy  would  derive  a  substantial  cumulative  benefit  from 
counter-cyclical  fiscal  action  initiated  by  the  provincial  government.  If  some  or 
all  other  provinces  were  encouraged  to  undertake  co-ordinated  fiscal  action,  the 
dimensions  of  leakages  would  be  sharply  diminished  and  the  benefits  accruing  to 
the  Canadian  economy  substantially  increased. 

34.  We  support  the  view  that  "perhaps  the  key  factor  in  determining  whether 
a  province  can  pursue  an  independent  fiscal  policy  is  the  nature  of  the  provinces' 
borrowing  capacity  and  the  extent  to  which  they  can  increase  their  debt",*^  in  order 
to  finance  the  deficits  that  constitute  an  inherent  component  of  such  a  policy.  The 
appropriate  magnitude  of  such  deficits  will  of  course  be  related  to  the  severity  of 
the  cyclical  fluctuations  that  beset  the  economy,  and  here  it  appears  reasonable 
to  assume,  on  the  basis  of  Canadian  post-war  experience,  that  the  typical  recession 
will  involve  some  relatively  moderate  decline  or  perhaps  temporary  cessation 
in  the  economy's  underlying  rate  of  economic  growth.  Our  studies  support  the 
view  that  in  such  circumstances,  and  indeed  in  the  somewhat  less  probable  event 
of  more  serious  and  prolonged  recession,  the  fiscal  strength  of  the  Province  of 
Ontario  makes  feasible  an  effective  program  of  provincial  counter-cycUcal  financ- 
ing. We  return  to  some  of  the  debt  implications  of  such  a  program  in  later 
sections  of  this  chapter  and  we  wish  to  emphasize  again  our  underlying  assumption 
that  in  such  periods  of  recession,  effective  monetary  and  fiscal  leadership  will  be 
provided  by  the  central  government.  On  this  latter  point,  we  agree  that  ".  .  .  it  is 
virtually  certain  that  in  any  future  period  of  cyclical  decline,  the  central  bank  [of 
Canada]  wifl  pursue  a  policy  of  monetary  ease  and  this  will  benefit  junior  levels  of 
government  as  well  as  the  central  government."'' 

35.  At  any  given  time,  the  "borrowing  capacity"  of  a  government  relates  both 
to  the  general  availability  and  to  the  cost  of  credit,  and  fundamentally  it  rests 
upon  the  government's  taxing  potential,  the  measure  of  its  ability  to  meet  the 
debt  obligations  that  it  may  incur.  Availability  may  also  be  affected  to  an 
important  degree  by  certain  customs  and  preferences  found  in  the  capital  market 
and  in  particular  by  the  traditional  views  of  financial  intermediaries  as  to  what 
constitutes  the  most  appropriate  distribution  of  their  asset  portfolios,  i.e.  of  their 
patterns  of  lending.  Such  traditions  are  particularly  strong  within  the  Canadian 
market.  As  a  means  of  escaping  either  the  real  or  the  assumed  domestic  limits 
of  their  borrowing  capacity,  provincial  and  municipal  governments  in  Canada 
have  frequently  turned  to  foreign  borrowing  in  the  U.S.  capital  market,  a  process 


"Barber,  Provincial  Fiscal  Policy,  p.  27. 
'Ihid..  p.  28. 


70 


Chapter  3:  Paragraphs  33-39 

that  necessarily  involves  the  assumption  of  exchange  risks  by  the  borrowers,  who 
are  committed  to  meeting  their  debt  obligations  in  foreign  currency. 

36.  Because  the  financial  community  has  judged  Ontario's  economy  to  be 
sound  and  the  conduct  of  its  financial  affairs  to  be  prudent,  the  Province  has  at 
no  time  during  the  post-war  years  been  called  upon  to  test  the  quantitative  limits 
of  its  borrowing  capacity.  The  most  significant  borrowing  limitation  has  rather 
been  found  in  the  reaction  of  the  government  to  rising  rates  of  interest  associated 
with  any  rapid  and  substantial  increase  in  provincial  debt.  While  the  general 
level  of  interest  rates  in  the  economy  will  reflect  the  relationship  between  the 
demand  for  and  the  supply  of  loanable  funds  (the  latter  influenced  strongly  by 
the  federal  government's  prevailing  monetary  policy),  the  cost  of  such  funds  to  a 
particular  province  will  be  further  influenced  by  the  degree  to  which  its  debt 
management  conforms  to  rather  arbitrary  criteria  of  "orthodoxy",  as  determined 
by  the  lenders.  There  is  therefore  reason  to  believe  that  a  major  limitation  on 
provincial  borrowing  is  not  the  existence  of  high  interest  rates  per  se  but  the  fear 
that  to  proceed  beyond  rather  arbitrary  limits  will  involve  a  rise  in  rates  relative 
to  those  of  other  provinces,  an  occurrence  interpreted  as  an  undesirable  reflection 
upon  the  financial  reputation  of  the  government. 

37.  In  the  context  of  counter-cyclical  finance  designed  to  combat  recession  in 
Canada,  one  may  reasonably  expect  that  a  constructive  complementary  policy  of 
monetary  expansion  by  the  federal  government  will  lower  the  general  level  of 
interest  rates  and  increase  the  money  supply  within  the  economy.  Given  the 
typical  decline  in  the  amount  of  private  corporate  borrowing  during  recession  and 
the  need  of  institutional  lenders  to  maintain  a  satisfactory  level  and  distribution 
of  their  earning  assets,  it  should  be  possible  for  governments,  and  particularly  for 
a  strong  provincial  government  such  as  Ontario,  to  expand  their  indebtedness 
substantially  and  at  relatively  low  interest  costs. 

38.  Recent  years  have  brought  an  encouraging  growth  in  the  general  under- 
standing of  the  potential  contribution  of  government  counter-cyclical  finance  and 
particularly  of  the  economic  role  of  government  deficits  in  periods  of  recession.  It 
is  nevertheless  obvious  that  there  exists  a  formidable  problem  of  public  education 
in  this  matter,  and  that  a  sustained  attack  by  all  feasible  means  is  required,  if  such 
a  program  is  to  develop  the  broadly  based  support  essential  to  its  long-term 
operation.  It  is  perhaps  not  too  much  to  hope  that  if  positively  pursued  by 
Ontario  and  other  provincial  governments,  financial  policies  directed  to  economic 
stabilization  may  very  soon  be  commonly  accepted  as  an  essential  component  of 
responsible  provincial  fiscal  action.  In  thus  promoting  a  new  orthodoxy,  such 
governments  might  finally  win  the  positive  support  of  the  financial  community  and 
escape  the  traditional  disfavour  that  the  incurring  of  deficits  has  long  brought 
upon  them. 

39.  Apart  from  considerations  related  to  the  availability  and  cost  of  funds, 
government  debt  policy  is  obviously  conditioned  by  prevailing  views  as  to  the 
particular  circumstances  in  which  it  will  be  appropriate  to  borrow.  These  views 
are  formulated  by  provincial  governments  in  the  light  of  their  systems  of  public 

71 


Provincial  Fiscal  Policy  and  Public  Borrowing 

accounting  which  commonly  distinguish  "ordinary"  from  "capital"  expenditures 
according  to  arbitrary  and  frequently  changing  criteria.  Granted  the  legislative 
and  administrative  advantages  of  such  a  classification,  it  not  only  fails  completely 
to  provide  any  basis  for,  but  in  a  sense  obstructs,  any  analysis  of  the  economic 
impact  of  government  expenditures  and  the  net  financial  effects  that  these  may 
bring  about. 

40.  To  utilize  the  provincial  public  accounts  as  an  effective  instrument  for 
economic  policy — and  it  is  our  view  that  such  action  should  not  be  longer  delayed 
— what  is  required  is  the  addition  of  a  national-accounts  approach  to  the  classifica- 
tion of  government  revenues  and  expenditures.  In  such  a  presentation,  only  (and 
all)  those  income  and  expenditure  transactions  of  the  government  that  provide  a 
direct  and  immediate  impact  on  the  total  flow  of  income  and  expenditure  through- 
out the  economy  would  be  included  in  a  national-accounts  form  of  budget.  Purely 
financial  transactions  (government  borrowing  and  lending  transactions,  which 
affect  only  the  asset  and  liability  positions  of  various  sectors  of  the  economy) 
would  be  excluded,  as  would  various  bookkeeping  items  solely  of  internal  signi- 
ficance to  the  government.  Moreover,  all  national-accounts  items  would  be  entered 
on  an  accrual  basis,  to  ".  .  .  permit  a  more  meaningful  appreciation  of  the  timing 
of  changes  in  the  surplus  or  deficit  of  the  government  sector  in  relation  to 
fluctuations  in  economic  activity."^*' 

41.  In  a  somewhat  more  general  context,  we  may  say  that  the  effectiveness  of 
government  economic  policy  will  depend  upon  the  skill  with  which  available  policy 
"instruments"  are  directed  to  the  attainment  of  a  well-defined  pattern  of  economic 
priorities.  In  today's  complex  economy,  the  skilful  use  of  fiscal  and  other  instru- 
ments requires  the  prompt  diagnosis  of  the  current  state  of  the  economy  and  of 
its  prospective  trends,  in  relation  to  the  public's  desired  goals.  It  also  requires  a 
thorough  understanding  of  the  capabilities  of  various  instruments  and  of  the 
particular  impact  of  alternative  policies  on  the  functioning  of  the  economy.  In 
short,  effective  economic  policy  requires  that  appropriate  technical  expertise  be 
available  to  government,  to  provide  the  relevant  information  on  which  sound 
policy  must  rest. 

42.  We  are  greatly  encouraged  to  observe  that  with  its  continuously  growing 
responsibility  for  promoting  provincial  and  national  economic  objectives,  the 
government  of  Ontario  has  been  moving  to  broaden  its  technical  resources  in  this 
important  area.  We  note  the  constructive  development  of  a  provmcial  "bureau 
of  statistics"  to  provide  a  range  of  economic  data  not  hitherto  available  to  the 
Province,  and  we  think  that  its  potential  will  be  most  fully  realized  through  the 
establishment  of  close  co-operation  with  the  present  Dominion  Bureau  and  with 
other  provincial  centres  of  economic  research.  Such  co-operation  is  particularly 
important  in  the  development  of  complementary  programs  of  research  and  of 
comparability  in  research  concepts,  techniques  and  choice  of  data.  We  believe 
that  the  continuing  development  of  such  an  economics  research  program  under  the 


'"See  Minister  of  Finance,  Budget  Speech,  Ottawa,  March  16,  1964,  pp.  59-63;  April  26, 
1965,  pp.  31-3.  See  also  U.S.  Congress,  The  Federal  Budget  as  an  Economic  Docu- 
ment, Washington:  U.S.  Government  Printing  Office,  1963. 

72 


Chapter  3:  Paragraphs  40-46 

recently  appointed  provincial  Chief  Economist  can  greatly  strengthen  the  govern- 
ment's position  in  weighing  complex  issues  of  economic  policy. 

PHILOSOPHIES  OF  PUBLIC  BORROWING 

43.  The  attitudes  that  underlie  the  borrowing  practices  of  provincial  and 
municipal  authorities  in  Canada  have  recently  been  the  subject  of  extensive  investi- 
gation and  analysis  by  the  federal  Royal  Commission  on  Banking  and  Finance, 
whose  findings  are  readily  available  for  those  readers  who  may  wish  to  pursue  the 
subject  in  some  detail.  ^^  They  confirm  the  existence  of  several  commonly  held 
and  somewhat  conflicting  "theories"  of  borrowing  which  we  shall  summarize  very 
briefly. 

44.  The  "future-generations"  theory  holds  that  because  the  benefits  of  present 
capital  expenditures  will  accrue  in  large  measure  to  future  generations  of  citizens, 
it  will  always  be  appropriate  to  rely  heavily  on  borrowing  as  a  means  of  financing 
such  expenditures.  The  choice  between  taxation  and  borrowing  is  therefore  seen 
primarily  as  a  means  of  distributing  the  burden  of  cost  of  capital  expenditures  as 
between  the  present  and  future  generations,  and  this  widely  held  view  has  greatly 
influenced  government  borrowing  decisions  at  many  levels,  times  and  places. 

45.  It  is  perhaps  unnecessary  to  point  out  that  regardless  of  the  means  of 
finance  adopted,  the  financial  and  real  resources  required  to  carry  through  the 
capital  project  must  be  supplied  by  the  contemporary  generation,  whether  through 
taxation  or  by  lending  to  the  government.  The  choice  of  financing  will  in  no  way 
alter  the  fact  that  the  human  and  material  resources  required  to  construct  a  school, 
hospital,  road  or  other  capital  facility  must  be  contributed  at  the  time  of  construc- 
tion. The  real  or  resource  cost  of  the  project  lies  in  the  diversion  of  resources 
from  other  potential  kinds  of  production  to  the  particular  objects  of  government 
expenditure,  and  it  is  quite  clear  that  no  part  of  this  cost  can  be  transferred  from 
one  generation  to  the  next.  However,  it  may  well  be  that  if  various  forms  of  social 
capital  are  constructed  when  the  economy  is  afllicted  by  substantial  unemployment, 
there  may  be  little  or  no  resource  cost  involved,  since  the  labour  and  other 
resources  used  in  public  construction  might  very  likely  have  remained  unemployed 
had  a  demand  not  been  created  by  government. 

46.  If  we  define  the  burden  of  a  particular  policy  of  public  finance  in  terms 
of  its  effects  upon  the  productive  capacity  of  any  given  generation,  then  the  choice 
of  financing,  as  between  taxation  and  borrowing,  becomes  important,  in  that  debt 
financing  will  involve  at  least  some  shifting  of  burden  from  the  present  to  the 
future.  In  the  first  place,  government  borrowing  may  impinge  more  heavily  on 
private  saving,  taxation  more  heavily  on  consumption.  The  effect  of  borrowing  is 
therefore  likely  to  be  that  current  consumption  is  relatively  little  impaired,  while 
the  rate  of  private  capital  formation  is  reduced.  This  will  in  all  likelihood 
reduce   the   capital   endowment   inherited   by    a   succeeding   generation    and    so 

"See  A.  W.  Johnson  and  J.  M.  Andrews,  "The  Basis  and  Effects  of  Provincial-Municipal 
Fiscal  Decisions",  in  Canadian  Tax  Foundation,  Inter-Government  Fiscal  Relationships, 
Toronto,  1964,  pp.  37-77.  This  study  was  undertaken  as  a  part  of  the  research  pro- 
gram of  the  recent  Canadian  Royal  Commission  on  Banking  and  Finance. 

73 


Provincial  Fiscal  Policy  and  Public  Borrowing 

adversely  affect  its  potential  consumption.  To  the  extent  that  this  occurs,  the 
burden  of  debt  financing  by  one  generation  will  have  been  shifted  to  the  future.  A 
similar  shifting  will  occur  if  the  higher  taxation  of  future  periods  impairs  the  rate 
of  capital  formation  or  lessens  the  efficiency  of  production  at  that  time. 

47.  A  second  aspect  of  inter-generation  shifting  relates  to  the  postponement  of 
taxation  which  borrowing  permits.  It  may  be  argued  that  the  actual  process  of 
lending  involves  no  burden  upon  the  creditor,  who  has  simply  undertaken  a 
voluntary  exchange  of  assets.  On  the  other  hand,  taxation  does  involve  a  real 
burden,  because  a  compulsory  surrender  of  wealth  occurs.  Because  the  related 
processes  of  borrowing  and  taxation  (to  service  and  to  repay  the  debt)  are 
distinct  in  time,  there  will  be  a  transfer  of  burden  from  the  present  to  the  future. 
It  should  be  noted  that  this  will  be  so  whether  the  main  impact  of  the  transfer 
of  private  resources  borrowed  by  the  government  has  been  reflected  in  reduced 
consumption  or  in  reduced  private  capital  formation.  One  important  qualification 
to  this  process  of  tax  postponement  and  accompanying  shift  of  burden  arises 
where  the  tax  base  utilized  in  servicing  and  repaying  the  debt  is  a  marketable 
asset  that  exists  at  the  time  the  debt  is  incurred.  This  is  strikingly  true  of 
municipalities,  where  real  property  constitutes  the  major  tax  base,  but  the 
qualification  is  much  less  relevant  to  the  provincial  tax  system.  In  the  municipal 
situation,  it  is  very  Hkely  that  the  necessary  future  tax  increases  will  be  anticipated 
and,  as  the  economists  say,  "capitalized",  with  a  consequent  fall  in  the  present 
market  value  of  the  property  on  which  the  tax  is  based.  The  result  will  be  that 
the  current  generation  of  real  property  owners  will  be  burdened  in  a  manner  not 
greatly  different  from  that  which  would  have  occurred  had  taxation  been  chosen 
initially  as  the  means  of  financing  the  public  capital  outlays. 

48.  The  foregoing  discussion  suggests  that  while  the  withdrawal  of  resources 
from  the  private  sector  of  the  economy  must  occur  at  the  time  that  social  capital 
projects  are  constructed,  some  inter-generation  transfer  of  burden  will  nevertheless 
be  occasioned  by  debt  financing.  Considerations  of  equity  suggest  that  this  result 
will  be  appropriate  wherever  a  significant  inter-generation  transfer  of  benefits  is 
conferred  by  such  projects.  An  obvious  and  inescapable  consequence  of  the 
choice  as  between  taxation  and  borrowing  is  that  it  will  affect  the  distribution  of 
the  community's  income  in  both  present  and  future  periods,  until  the  debt  has 
been  repaid.  The  choice  therefore  affects  the  distribution  of  burden  both  within 
and  among  successive  generations. 

49.  In  contrast  to  the  foregoing  position,  the  "pay-as-you-go"  view  maintains 
that  government  should  normally  finance  both  its  operating  and  capital  expendi- 
tures from  revenues.  If  no  exceptions  are  admitted,  this  represents  the  traditional 
annually-balanced-budget  approach,  the  glaring  economic  weaknesses  of  which 
have  increasingly  become  recognized.  Proponents  of  this  view  nevertheless  usually 
interpret  it  in  sufficiently  broad  fashion  to  permit  the  debt  financing  of  such  self- 
liquidating  capital  projects  as  provincial  and  municipal  utilities,  local  improvements 
assessed  to  beneficiaries,  and  the  like.  Where  the  "self-liquidating"  criterion  is 
extended   to  include   public   expenditures   designed    to   provide   rather   long-run 

74 


Chapter  3:  Paragraphs  47-52 

returns  as,  for  example,  in  education,  the  practical  significance  of  the  pay-as-you- 
go  formula  becomes  very  vague  indeed. 

50.  It  is  our  considered  opinion  that  self-liquidating  provincial  and  municipal 
capital  projects — that  is  to  say,  projects  that  produce  an  early  and  predictable 
steady  flow  of  income  sufficient  to  meet  their  cost — may  appropriately  be  financed 
by  borrowing.  We  note,  however,  that  various  public  utilities  estabUshed  with  the 
intention  of  becoming  self-liquidating  frequently  fail  to  achieve  such  a  financial 
status  or,  having  achieved  it,  fail  to  maintain  it.  This  being  so,  it  cannot  be 
arbitrarily  assumed  that  any  proposed  public  project  will  most  appropriately  be 
financed  entirely  by  borrowing,  simply  because  it  is  conventionally  regarded  as 
being  self-hquidating.  What  is  required  is  a  thorough  analysis  of  the  prospective 
cost  and  revenue  patterns  of  the  proposed  enterprise  to  determine  its  possible  cost 
to  the  taxpayers.  Excluding  the  genuine  self-liquidating  category,  we  think  that 
neither  the  future-generations  argument  nor  the  pay-as-you-go  argument  provides 
a  satisfactory  basis  for  financing  capital  expenditure.  The  former  appears  to  imply 
that  all  such  expenditures  should  be  met  by  borrowing,  the  latter  that  none  should 
be  so  met,  each  representing  an  extreme  position  that  would  preclude  desirable 
fiscal  flexibility  in  adapting  to  the  changing  requirements  of  the  economy. 

51.  If  the  Province  of  Ontario  and  its  municipalities  were  confronted  by  the 
continuing  prospect  of  not  only  high  but  also  relatively  stable  levels  of  annual 
capital  expenditures,  or  of  rising  expenditures  at  relatively  stable  rates  of  growth, 
we  think  that  there  would  be  a  strong  case  for  these  governments  to  move  towards 
a  position  where  the  major  proportion  of  such  expenditures  was  normally  financed 
from  revenues,  including  grants.  Given  this  primary  emphasis,  the  revenue-debt 
relationship  adopted  by  any  particular  government  would  nevertheless  depend  on 
the  one  hand  upon  its  revenue  capabilities  and  on  the  other  hand  upon  its  borrow- 
ing capacity,  including  its  ability  to  sustain  the  increased  debt.  In  both  these 
respects,  the  position  of  the  municipalities  is  notably  less  satisfactory  than  that  of 
the  Province. 

52.  As  detailed  in  a  later  chapter  of  this  Report,  our  forecasts  of  provincial 
and  municipal  expenditures  in  Ontario  during  the  next  decade  confirm  the  necessity 
for  rapidly  escalating  capital  outlays  in  such  fields  as  education,  resource  develop- 
ment, and  roads  and  highways,  if  public  investment  is  to  succeed  in  making  its 
most  effective  contribution  to  increased  productivity  and  sustained  growth  within 
the  provincial  and  the  national  economy.  Given  these  spending  prospects,  not 
even  the  early  attainment  of  an  "ideal"  provincial-municipal  tax  system  would 
render  feasible  their  financing  on  a  pay-as-you-go  basis,  nor  indeed  would  such 
a  policy  be  defensible  in  principle.  In  any  growing  economy,  the  secular  rise  in 
tax  capacity  is  accompanied  by  a  comparable  rise  in  capacity  to  carry  debt  and 
both  sources  of  finance  must  be  utilized  as  part  and  parcel  of  a  sound  fiscal  policy. 
To  insist  in  such  circumstances  upon  an  unchanging  level  of  debt  (the  balanced- 
budget  fallacy)  is  to  restrict  unnecessarily  and  undesirably  the  ability  of  govern- 
ment to  finance  public  expenditure  and  to  ignore  the  need  of  the  economy  for  an 

75 


Provincial  Fiscal  Policy  and  Public  Borrowing 

increasing  stock  of  safe  and  liquid  assets  without  which  the  incentive  to  save 
might  well  be  weakened. 

53.  Viewing  the  prospect  of  both  provincial  and  municipal  expenditures  in 
Ontario  in  the  years  to  1975,  we  therefore  regard  a  substantial  absolute  increase 
in  debt  at  both  levels  of  government  not  simply  as  an  inevitable  but  as  a 
constructive  aspect  of  public  finance.  What  must  be  carefully  considered,  however, 
are  the  tolerable  limits  to  any  heavier  burden  that  may  be  involved  in  such 
increases,  and  here  we  think  that  in  view  of  recent  trends,  municipal  governments 
may  have  little  room  to  manoeuvre.  In  a  later  chapter  of  our  Report,  we  offer 
some  views  concerning  the  most  appropriate  behaviour  of  provincial  and  municipal 
debt  during  the  ensuing  decade. 

54.  Whatever  the  average  proportion  of  Ontario's  capital  expenditures  to  be 
financed  by  borrowing  through  the  years  to  1975,  the  most  appropriate  debt  policy 
at  any  particular  time  will  reflect  the  current  state  of  the  provincial  economy  and 
the  indicated  need  for  counter-cyclical  fiscal  measures.  Moreover,  in  view  of  the 
magnitude  of  aggregate  municipal  expenditures  within  Ontario,  the  effective  use 
of  provincial  fiscal  policy  will  require  some  measures  to  ensure  that  budgetary 
changes  at  the  municipal  level  complement  rather  than  conflict  with  provincial 
policy. 

MUNICIPAL  FINANCE 

55.  In  this  connection,  we  think  it  quite  unreahstic  to  expect  any  municipality 
to  initiate  counter-cycHcal  fiscal  measures,  for  it  will  have  neither  the  competence, 
nor  the  financial  resources,  nor  the  incentive  to  adopt  such  a  policy.  Yet  a  very  few 
Ontario  municipalities  account  for  a  very  large  proportion  of  total  municipal 
expenditures  within  the  province,  and  the  advantages  of  modifying  the  timing  of 
such  expenditures  in  order  to  achieve  some  stabilizing  influence  on  the  general 
level  of  economic  activity  are  obvious.  While  the  urgent  need  for  schools,  hospitals, 
roads,  sewerage  systems  and  other  forms  of  social  capital  renders  the  postponement 
of  many  municipal  outlays  impracticable,  it  is  reasonable  to  suppose  that  in  any 
given  period  some  of  these  municipal  expenditures  are  optional  and  therefore 
potentially  subject  to  deferment.  Our  prime  emphasis  is  nevertheless  somewhat 
different  in  that,  given  the  sound  planning  of  all  such  expenditures  through  five- 
year  capital  budgets,  we  think  that  sufficient  flexibility  might  be  introduced  to 
make  the  advancement  of  particular  projects  a  reaUstic  possibility. 

56.  As  a  comprehensive  fiscal  planning  document,  the  five-year  budget  has 
been  the  object  of  considerable  study  by  senior  levels  of  government  in  recent 
years.  It  is  viewed  not  as  a  replacement  for  the  present  one-year  budgeting  practice 
but  as  a  supplementary  instrument  designed  to  improve  the  quality  of  fiscal 
decisions  in  regard  to  both  taxation  and  expenditure.  Subject  to  the  inherent  risks 
of  forecasting  in  these  areas,  the  multiple-year  budget  permits  a  more  rational 
assessment  of  the  implications  of  fiscal  proposals  than  the  one-year  budget  can 
possibly  do,  and  it  can  be  modified  continuously  by  a  process  of  annual  revision. 
We  think  it  entirely  possible  that  through  the  extended  application  of  the  five-year 

76 


Chapter  3:  Paragraphs  53-57 

budget  to  municipal  capital  planning  within  Ontario,  significant  variations  in 
aggregate  municipal  expenditures  might  be  achieved,  in  relation  to  changes  in 
the  underlying  state  of  the  provincial  economy. 

57.  To  effect  this  desired  integration  of  municipal  with  provincial  fiscal 
policies,  the  municipalities  will  need  to  be  provided  not  only  with  the  necessary 
technical  expertise  but  with  appropriate  financial  assistance,  and  here  we  have  no 
wish  to  minimize  the  problems  involved.  We  think  that  municipal  governments 
in  Ontario  can  most  effectively  be  made  partners  in  the  counter-cyclical  timing  of 
their  capital  projects  through  arrangements  that  permit  the  advancement  in  time 
of  specified  capital  expenditures,  without  involving  these  municipalities  in  any 
corresponding  advancement  of  the  accompanying  financial  commitments.  In 
relation  to  the  process  of  five-year  capital  budgeting,  the  objective  of  the  provincial 
government  would  simply  be  to  alter  the  timing  of  capital  outlays  from  that 
already  contemplated  by  any  municipality  and  its  associated  local  boards  in  the 
absence  of  counter-cyclical  considerations.  The  Province  might  therefore  meet 
the  cost  of  the  municipality's  temporary  borrowing  for  a  specific  period  of  time, 
perhaps  initially  one  year,  in  relation  to  the  bringing  forward  of  municipal  capital 
projects  scheduled  for  a  later  period,  in  order  to  swell  the  aggregate  volume  of 
counter-cycUcal  capital  investment.  In  addition,  the  Province  would  also  need 
to  advance  its  own  grant  funds  for  which  such  projects  would  be  eligible,  as 
determined  by  the  normal  criteria  for  grant  assistance.  In  recent  years,  the  federal 
government  has  established  conditional  grant  programs  related  to  capital  projects 
faUing  within  municipal  jurisdiction.  In  part,  their  objective  has  been  to  reduce 
unemployment,  but  they  have  not  in  practice  been  effectively  geared  to  cyclical 
objectives,  nor  have  the  available  financial  resources  been  most  effectively  allocated. 
We  think  that  the  manifest  interest  of  the  federal  government  in  a  broadly 
co-ordinated  program  of  social  capital  expenditure  can  best  be  reconciled  with 
provincial-municipal  priorities  in  this  area,  not  by  direct  federal  grants  to  the 
municipalities,  but  by  an  appropriate  flow  of  such  funds  to  the  provinces.  The 
provinces  will  thereby  be  strengthened  in  the  financing  and  administering  of  their 
own  counter-cyclical  measures  on  behalf  of  themselves  and  their  municipalities. 


77 


Chapter 

4 


The  Ontario  Setting: 
Patterns  of  Expenditure, 
Revenue  and  Debt 


INTRODUCTION 

1.  Death  and  taxes  appear  to  be  inescapable  facts  of  life.  Medical  science  has 
done  much  to  postpone  the  inevitability  of  death,  but  the  fatalism  with  which  we 
have  come  to  accept  taxation  is  underlined  for  us  by  the  long  interval  of  over  sixty 
years  that  separates  our  inquiries  from  those  of  our  most  closely  related  prede- 
cessor, the  Ontario  Assessment  Commission  of  1900.  That  body,  familiarly  known 
as  the  Maclennan  Commission,  concentrated  exclusively  on  municipal  taxation. 
At  the  time,  provincial  taxes  were  few  and  made  only  moderate  contributions  to 
government  revenue.  Comprehensive  taxes  on  income  and  consumption  were  still 
clouds  no  bigger  than  a  man's  hand  hovering  on  the  distant  horizon.  The  very 
environment  in  which  the  Maclennan  Commission  conducted  its  work  transports  us 
into  a  nostalgic  era.  Thus  the  September  14,  1900,  edition  of  the  Toronto  Daily 
Star,  in  which  the  appointment  of  the  Commission  was  announced,  carried  an 
Eaton's  advertisement  offering  good  quality  men's  suits  at  $8.50  to  $10.  Shirt 
collars  retailed  at  500  to  750,  and  cloth-bound  novels  by  such  authors  as  Arthur 
Conan  Doyle,  James  Fenimore  Cooper  and  George  Eliot  were  on  sale  at  half  their 
usual  200  price.    Also  in  stock  at  Eaton's  were  100  cuspidors  of  finest  quality 


79 


The  Ontario  Setting 

granite,  originally  priced  at  350  but  selling  for  150  "while  they  last".  In  another 
Star  advertisement  reluctant  businessmen  were  told  "The  Telephone  is  the  Business 
Agency  of  the  Century.    See  that  you  are  associated  with  it." 

2.  Needless  to  say,  the  passing  years  have  wrought  so  many  changes  in  the 
province  and  in  the  responsibilities  that  governments  are  called  upon  to  assume  that 
we  cannot  use  our  predecessor's  report  as  a  foundation  for  our  own  findings  and 
conclusions.  Because  the  environmental  setting  for  our  investigation  has  altered  so 
radically,  it  seems  essential,  as  a  prelude  to  our  detailed  studies,  to  sketch  the 
main  elements  of  growth  and  change  in  Ontario.  It  is,  after  all,  the  changing  modes 
of  life  and  employment  that  have  so  drastically  affected  the  revenue  and  expenditure 
patterns  of  the  government  and  so  provide  the  main  point  of  reference  for  our 
inquiry  into  taxation  policies  and  practices. 

3.  It  is  appropriate  to  begin  what  may  be  described  as  a  remarkable  success 
story  with  the  province's  chief  resource:  its  people.  We  then  proceed  to  observe  the 
ways  in  which  the  populace  has  deployed  its  knowledge,  skills  and  productive 
capacities  throughout  a  territorial  domain  exceeding  four  hundred  thousand  square 
miles,  but  with  a  concentration  of  forces  in  a  southern  section  that  represents  less 
than  one-eighth  of  the  total  area.  From  this  assessment  we  can  identify  the  chang- 
ing activities  and  the  growing  social  needs  that  have  resulted  in  adding  to  the 
traditionally  protective  and  essentially  limited  responsibilities  of  government  a 
multitude  of  new  welfare,  servicing  and  regulatory  functions.  The  expansion  of 
government  services  and  the  population's  increasing  reliance  on  a  high  and  efficient 
level  of  such  services  have  swollen  provincial  and  municipal  expenditures  and 
correspondingly  tested  the  ingenuity  of  those  responsible  for  finding  the  necessary 
revenues.  These  are  the  essential  elements  of  the  environment  within  which  our 
study  of  taxation  has  been  undertaken.  The  ways  in  which  governments  go  about 
the  task  of  raising  the  funds  necessary  to  meet  their  growing  range  of  commitments 
— that  is,  their  taxation  policies  and  practices — can  have  a  marked  impact  on  most 
elements  of  the  environment.  By  the  same  token,  and  as  this  chapter  seeks  to 
demonstrate,  the  environmental  setting  establishes  certain  facts  of  life  to  which  the 
system  of  taxation  must  be  adapted. 

THE  POPULATION  OF  ONTARIO 
SIZE,  COMPOSITION  AND  DISTRIBUTION 

4.  When  the  Maclennan  Commission  undertook  its  investigation  of  municipal 
taxation  in  1900,  the  population  of  Ontario  was  less  than  one-third  its  present 
size  of  over  seven  million.  In  1900,  three  out  of  every  four  persons  lived  in 
a  rural  setting;  today,  the  proportion  of  urban  dwellers  has  completely  reversed 
the  earlier  picture.  Even  this  dramatic  transformation  from  rural  to  urban 
dwelling  does  not  reveal  the  extent  to  which  we  have  tended  to  congregate  in  a  few 
large  metropolitan  centres.  At  the  turn  of  the  century,  Toronto  had  added  only 
3,000  persons  over  the  past  thirty  years  to  bring  its  total  population  to  59,000. 
Hamilton,  Ottawa  and  London  each  had  less  than  half  this  figure.  Today  the 
metropolitan  centres  of  Toronto  and  Hamilton  together  account  for  one-third  of 

80 


Chapter  4:  Paragraphs  2-8 

the  total  population  of  the  province.  Nearly  one-half  of  the  population  is  now 
located  in  the  "golden  horseshoe"  of  urban  centres  extending  from  Oshawa  to 
Niagara.  It  is  surely  unnecessary  to  dwell  on  the  implications  of  this  new  pattern  of 
living  for  the  municipal  governments  that  must  provide  increasingly  sophisticated 
and  expensive  services  for  these  points  of  rapid  urban  growth. 

5.  Native-bom  residents  of  Ontario  appear  to  find  their  increasingly  urbanized 
mode  of  life  congenial :  at  least  it  can  be  said  that  the  proportion  of  them  who  seek 
residence  elsewhere  in  Canada  is  smaller  than  the  proportion  of  those  from  other 
provinces  who  migrate  to  Ontario.  Similarly,  reversing  a  pattern  of  the  past,  more 
than  half  of  the  immigrants  who  now  come  to  Canada  choose  Ontario  as  their  final 
destination.  Thus  today,  over  one  in  five  residents  of  the  province  is  foreign-bom — 
a  phenomenon  that  has  not  gone  unnoticed  in  larger  metropolitan  centres,  whose 
character  now  bears  a  distinctly  cosmopolitan  imprint. 

6.  Advances  in  medical  science  and  public  health  measures  have  affected  the 
age  distribution  of  the  population,  with  far-reaching  consequences  for  the  future 
labour  force  of  the  community  and  with  immediate  repercussions  for  the  govern- 
ment in  such  fields  as  education,  housing,  health  and  welfare.  In  general,  we  are 
an  older  people  than  we  were  at  the  turn  of  the  century,  largely  because  relatively 
more  people  live  out  their  biblical  span  of  three  score  years  and  ten.  The  rate  of 
family  formation,  which  in  turn  govems  the  number  of  children  in  the  population, 
is  now  ascending  again,  after  a  brief  decline  that  set  in  after  the  rapid  formation 
of  families  during  the  war  years  and  the  consequent  "baby  boom".  We  can  antici- 
pate a  repetition  of  the  post-war  cycle  to  bear  fruit — and  raise  govemmental 
expenditures — in  the  1970's.  Meanwhile,  although  the  proportion  of  young  people 
in  today's  population  is  not  as  large  as  it  was  at  the  turn  of  the  century,  we  are  still 
faced  with  the  fact  that  the  number  of  school-age  children  today  is  nearly  as  large 
as  was  the  total  population  of  the  province  in  1900. 

7.  An  increasingly  urbanized  population  places  municipal  services  of  all  kinds 
under  severe  pressure,  even  as  a  growing  number  of  elderly  people  focuses  attention 
on  health,  welfare  and  social  insurance  schemes,  and  as  the  burgeoning  crop  of 
young  people  compels  governments  to  take  costly  measures  to  provide  adequate 
educational  faciUties.  When  we  add  that  an  extraordinarily  large  proportion  of  the 
population  virtually  lives  on  wheels,  spending  annually  over  two-thirds  of  a  billion 
dollars  on  new  passenger  automobiles,  we  have  indeed  moved  a  long  way  from  the 
halcyon  horse-and-buggy  days  of  the  early  1900's  when  fewer  than  two  hundred 
vehicles  were  registered  for  the  entire  province.  The  design,  construction  and  main- 
tenance of  a  network  of  highways  and  streets  sufficient  to  girdle  the  globe  more  than 
twice  over  are  but  some  of  the  direct  costs  of  the  automobile  age  for  which  govern- 
ments at  all  levels  must  find  financial  resources  and  technical  skills.  The  indirect 
costs  from  pollution,  congestion,  and  traffic  accidents  are  only  now  beginning  to 
take  their  place  on  the  agenda  of  government. 

ECONOMIC  ACTIVITIES 

8.  Dramatic  and  extensive  as  are  the  changes  this  century  has  wrought  in  the 
size,  composition  and  distribution  of  the  province's  population,  they  are  in  large 

81 


The  Ontario  Setting 

measure  responses  to  important  transformations  that  have  been  taking  place  in  the 
economy  and  in  the  occupations  that  people  have  come  to  pursue.  The  shift  to 
urban  living  is  in  an  important  sense  a  measure  of  the  substantial  decUne  in  the 
relative  importance  of  agriculture  as  an  occupation.  At  the  turn  of  the  century 
there  were  nearly  twice  as  many  people  employed  in  agriculture  as  there  are  today. 
This  greatly  reduced  agricultural  labour  force,  occupying  somewhat  reduced  acre- 
age but  on  many  fewer  farm  units,  has  nevertheless  managed  to  quadruple  the  net 
value  of  farm  production  over  the  last  sixty  years.  It  should  also  be  noted  that 
farm  production  is  no  longer  destined  for  export  but  is  used  domestically  to  feed 
the  urban  population  and  to  provide  the  raw  materials  for  local  food-processing 
concerns  such  as  bakeries,  packing  plants,  flour  mills  and  distilleries  that  either  did 
not  exist  or  were  very  small  in  1 900.  On  the  other  hand,  agriculture  today  contrib- 
utes only  6.8  per  cent  to  the  net  value  generated  from  all  commodity-producing 
industries,  and  its  share  of  the  labour  force  has  declined  from  more  than  one-third 
to  less  than  one-tenth  of  the  total. 

9.  Even  as  the  decline  in  agricultural  employment  is  an  indication  of  the  extent 
to  which  we  have  become  urban  dwellers,  so  the  shift  to  urbanization  has  been 
associated  with  the  growth  of  employment  in  other  occupations.  The  most  signifi- 
cant change  has  occurred  in  the  service  industries.  These  industries,  which  include 
transportation,  trade,  finance  and  public  utilities,  now  employ  more  than  half  the 
labour  force.  Nearly  another  third  of  the  labour  force  is  employed  in  manufacturing, 
which  contributes  in  gross  value  of  production,  after  allowing  for  inflation  of  prices, 
fifteen  times  the  amount  it  contributed  sixty  years  ago.  The  construction  industry 
now  employs  about  two-thirds  the  number  in  agriculture,  and  accounts  for  6  per 
cent  of  total  employment. 

10.  The  significant  shifts  in  occupation  that  have  occurred  since  1900  have 
reduced  the  proportion  of  self-employed  persons  as  more  and  more  members  of  the 
labour  force  find  themselves  employed  by  large  concerns  and  paid  in  wages  and 
salaries.  This  change  in  status  may  in  large  part  account  for  growing  public 
acceptance  of  the  need  for  government  intervention  in  labour  disputes,  and  for  new 
or  expanded  unemployment  insurance  schemes,  pension  plans,  medical  insurance 
programs  and  other  public  welfare  measures. 

11.  Not  only  has  the  pattern  of  gainful  employment  altered  as  indicated,  but 
the  composition  of  the  labour  force  itself  has  undergone  substantial  changes. 
Perhaps  the  most  significant  of  these  changes  is  the  extent  to  which  women  have 
been  enabled  to  enter  the  labour  force  by  virtue  of  time-saving  gadgetry,  com- 
munity acceptance  of  the  altered  role  of  women,  and  the  growth  of  service  industries 
more  suited  to  female  aptitudes  than  such  formerly  dominant  enterprises  as 
forestry  and  mining.  In  the  early  1 900's  women  made  up  one-seventh  of  the  labour 
force;  today  women  comprise  more  than  one-quarter  of  the  labour  force. 

12.  While  the  labour  force  as  a  whole  has  grown  to  the  point  where  it  consti- 
tutes some  40  per  cent  of  the  total  population,  actually  a  diminishing  proportion  of 
the  populace  has  been  entering  employment,  largely  because  the  younger  age 
groups  have  grown  in  numbers  and  because  young  people  tend  to  remain  longer  in 

82 


Chapter  4:  Paragraphs  9-14 

school  or  university.  The  acquisition  of  a  higher  level  of  education  and  advanced 
technical  training  is  consistent  with  the  demands  now  being  imposed  on  the  labour 
force  by  the  increased  complexity  of  our  productive  system.  Rising  output  must 
outpace  population  growth  if  we  are  to  enjoy  a  continuously  rising  standard  of 
living  and  have  the  capacity  to  pay  for  the  mounting  costs  of  more  and  better 
government  services.  For  their  part,  educational  and  training  facilities  must  keep 
up  with  the  needs  of  the  labour  force  if  productivity  is  to  be  sustained.  Here,  in  a 
nutshell,  is  a  dramatic  demonstration  of  the  unbroken  circle  of  mutual  interdepen- 
dence of  a  number  of  interests:  we  all  wish  to  enjoy  a  rising  standard  of  living, 
which  depends  on  increased  productivity,  which  can  only  be  secured  by  expanding 
the  facilities  and  time  required  to  acquire  the  necessary  education  and  training, 
which,  in  turn,  can  be  provided  only  by  governments  at  increasing  total  cost  to  the 
taxpayer,  who  can  sustain  these  costs  only  because  he  is  enjoying  a  rising  standard 
of  living!  Unfortunately,  investment  in  the  education  of  the  young  cannot  be  post- 
poned and,  if  members  of  the  present  generation  are  all  to  be  given  equal  oppor- 
tunities, the  mounting  burdens  on  our  educational  resources  and  on  governmental 
budgets  are  inescapable  as  well  as  desirable. 

13.  The  variety  and  scope  of  occupations  now  opened  up  to  the  populace  of 
Ontario  by  twentieth-century  developments  have  permitted  the  labour  force  of  this 
province  to  enjoy  the  highest  average  real  earnings  in  Canada.  The  cost  of  living 
today  may  appear  to  be  a  far  cry  from  tum-of-the-century  prices  when  books 
retailed  for  200  and  a  good  suit  could  be  purchased  for  less  than  $10.  On  the 
other  hand,  we  have  also  come  a  long  way  from  the  prevailing  average  labourer's 
wage  of  230  an  hour.  Today's  wage  earner  in  Ontario  probably  works  eight  to  ten 
hours  per  week  less  than  his  counterpart  in  1900,  has  perhaps  three  times  the 
purchasing  power,  enjoys  greater  security,  and  has  access  to  more  facilities  with 
which  to  enjoy  his  leisure.  The  "average"  resident  of  Ontario  occupies  his  own 
five-  to  six-room  house,  which  is  most  likely  to  be  heated  by  oil  or  gas,  and  supplied 
with  water  through  community  mains.  Stoves,  refrigerators,  radios,  television  sets 
and  washing  machines  can  be  found  in  over  80  per  cent  of  the  homes,  and  make 
Ontario  residents  among  the  highest  consumers  of  electrical  energy  in  the  world. 
Three-quarters  of  Ontario  families  own  at  least  one  automobile;  some  11  per  cent 
have  two  or  more.  Commanding  the  largest  share  of  after-tax  income  in  Canada, 
the  resident  of  Ontario  is  able  to  indulge  his  growing  leisure  time  in  foreign 
travel  or  recreational  pursuits. 

14.  Our  picture  of  the  people  of  Ontario  and  their  current  economic  activities 
as  producers  and  consumers  has  had  to  be  painted  in  broad  brush  strokes  that  tend 
to  ignore  the  disparities  between  regions  and  individuals.  But  what  this  sketch  does 
reveal  is  a  province  with  a  rapidly  growing,  urbanized  population,  a  varied  and 
increasingly  industrialized  economy  showing  a  pronounced  shift  away  from  its 
traditional  occupational  base  of  primary  and  extractive  industries,  and  a  transfer 
of  an  ever-increasing  volume  of  resources  to  all  the  supporting  service  industries 
required  in  such  an  economy.  It  shows  a  remarkable  concentration  of  population 
and  economic  activity  in  a  small  southerly  portion  of  a  very  large  territory.  It 
depicts  a  growing  generation  of  young  people  demanding  more  education  and 

83 


The  Ontario  Setting 

training  with  which  to  apply  the  new  science  and  technology  to  our  productive 
processes,  thereby  sustaining  increased  productivity.  It  reveals  a  labour  force 
enjoying  the  fruits  of  rapid  development,  with  more  time  and  money  to  make  the 
most  of  them.  Above  all,  our  sketch  has  demonstrated,  by  passing  references,  that 
nearly  all  these  changes  have  transformed  the  role  of  government  and  occasioned  a 
dramatic  rise  in  the  costs  of  government  services.  Since  this  transformation  lies  at 
the  heart  of  the  taxation  problems  confronting  this  Committee,  we  propose  to 
pursue  it  now  in  greater  detail. 

THE  CHANGING  ROLE  OF  GOVERNMENT 

15.  The  Province  of  Ontario  is  by  no  means  unique  in  its  exposure  to  the 
contemporary  forces  of  industrialization,  urbanization  and  secularization.  Nor  is 
it  alone  in  having  to  adapt  to  the  revolutionary  changes  in  science  and  technology 
that  have  brought  us  in  successive  leaps  through  the  eras  of  canals,  railways  and 
highways,  to  the  jet  and  outer-space  age  of  the  sixties.  Developments  in  the  field 
of  electronics  have  precipitated  radical  changes  in  communications  that  shrink  the 
world  and  bring  its  astounding  variety  of  events  visually  before  us  in  our  living 
rooms.  The  computer,  data  processing,  and  automation  in  all  their  complexity 
and  marvellous  versatility  open  new  vistas,  even  as  they  raise  such  major  prob- 
lems of  adjustment  as  the  retraining  of  the  labour  force.  The  energy  potential 
locked  in  the  atom  has  been  released  as  a  great  power  for  good  or  ill  in  the  world, 
and  this  achievement  coupled  with  improved  techniques  for  exploiting  conventional 
sources  of  energy  has  added  fresh  impetus  to  the  economy.  In  short,  we  are  being 
buffeted  by  an  unprecedented  flood  of  innovating  genius  that  creates  fresh  problems 
of  adaptation  and  adjustment,  even  as  it  opens  up  new  perspectives  and  oppor- 
tunities for  a  full  Hfe. 

16.  Increasingly,  people  have  come  to  look  to  governments  not  only  as  key 
sponsors  of  change  but,  perhaps  more  importantly,  as  their  buffer  against  the 
unremitting  and  unsettling  pressures  caused  by  change.  From  a  somewhat  passive 
protector  of  persons  and  property,  a  provider  of  law  and  order,  government  has 
been  thrust  into  new  roles  as  conciliator  of  social  conflicts,  guardian  of  health,  dis- 
tributor of  welfare,  regulator  of  major  sectors  of  the  market  place,  and  owner  and 
operator  of  commercial  enterprises.  Whereas  in  the  past  representative  legis- 
latures, an  independent  judiciary  aided  by  a  staunch  local  constabulary,  and  a  tiny 
cabinet  assisted  by  a  handful  of  civil  servants  could  be  expected  to  cope  with  the 
functions  traditionally  assigned  to  governments,  today  these  functions  have  multi- 
plied and  become  so  complex  that  they  command  the  full-time  attention  of 
thousands  of  specialists  working  in  an  ever-expanding  variety  of  administrative 
agencies.  Multi-level  government,  with  all  its  departments  and  agencies,  today 
emerges  as  the  single  largest  employer,  drawing  into  its  service  not  only  substan- 
tial numbers  of  clerical  workers  but  every  conceivable  type  of  professional  skill. 

17.  It  is  not  surprising  that  the  public  service  of  Ontario,  as  the  focal  point 
for  major  pressures  to  extend  the  reach  and  functions  of  government,  has  been 
affected  more  dramatically  than  any  other  compartment  of  government  by  the 

84 


Chapter  4:  Paragraphs  15-20 

forces  of  change  swirling  in  the  community.  A  legislature  that  numbered  ninety- 
four  members  in  1900  has  since  that  time  been  increased  by  the  addition  of  only 
fourteen  members,  while  its  traditional  methods  for  the  conduct  of  the  province's 
business  have  remained  essentially  unchanged.  On  the  other  hand,  a  cabinet  of 
nine  ministers  heading  eight  departments  that  was  adequate  for  the  executive 
responsibilities  at  the  turn  of  the  century  has  been  progressively  expanded  with 
each  new  area  of  responsibility  assumed  by  the  government.  Today,  we  find  a 
cabinet  comprising  twenty-three  ministers,  responsible  for  twenty-two  departments. 
A  list  of  the  departments  created  since  1915  represents  a  veritable  catalogue  of  the 
new  positive  functions  assumed  by  the  Province  of  Ontario  over  the  last  fifty  years. 
Beginning  with  a  Department  of  Highways  in  1915,  there  follow  in  chronological 
sequence  departments  of  Labour  (1919);  Insurance  (1924);  Health  (1924); 
Public  Welfare  (1931)  (changed  in  1967  to  Social  and  Family  Services);  Municipal 
Affairs  (1935);  Planning  and  Development  (1944)  (ultimately  becoming  Economics 
and  Development  in  1962);  Travel  and  Publicity  (1946)  (subsequently  transformed 
in  1964  to  Tourism  and  Information);  Reform  Institutions  (1946);  Transport 
(1957);  Energy  Resources  (1959)  (changed  in  1961  to  Energy  and  Resources 
Management);  Civil  Service  (1962);  University  Affairs  (1964);  and  most  recently, 
in  1966,  a  Department  of  Financial  and  Commercial  Affairs. 

18.  Even  this  expansion  of  the  executive  branch  does  not  reveal  the  full 
impact  of  the  positive  role  now  assumed  by  the  government,  for  we  must  also 
include  what  were  non-existent  in  1900:  a  multitude  of  boards,  commissions  and 
public  corporations.  These  agencies  have  been  allotted  many  of  those  functions  of 
government  which  were  virtually  unknown  to  the  earlier  civil  service:  regulation, 
stimulation  and  operation  of  certain  segments  of  the  province's  economy;  arbitra- 
tion of  conflicts  and  supervision  of  markets;  conservation  and  promotion  of  physi- 
cal resources;  the  buttressing  of  the  weak,  the  dependent  and  the  sick;  and  so  on. 

19.  Sheer  growth  in  the  number  of  public  employees  is  one  obvious  accompani- 
ment to  the  expanding  activities  and  the  increasing  number  of  government  agencies. 
The  total  numerical  strength  of  the  public  service  of  the  province  at  the  turn  of 
the  century  was  well  under  one  thousand;  that  is  to  say,  about  one-eighth  the 
size  of  the  contemporary  Department  of  Highways — a  department  that  did  not 
even  exist  in  1900.  In  absolute  terms  the  expansion  of  the  civil  service  has  been 
in  the  order  of  an  eighty-fold  increase  since  1900,  and  the  great  upward  thrust  has 
been  concentrated  in  the  years  following  the  Second  World  War.  This  expansion, 
to  be  kept  in  perspective,  should  be  viewed  in  the  context  of  the  increasing  share 
of  the  labour  force  taken  up  today  by  the  service  industries  as  a  whole.  In  relative 
terms,  however,  while  less  than  one  out  of  every  thousand  members  of  the  labour 
force  was  a  public  employee  in  1900,  the  proportion  is  now  roughly  thirty  out  of 
every  thousand. 

20.  These  figures  demonstrate  the  rapid  accretion  of  governmental  responsi- 
biUties  at  the  provincial  level  but  they  do  not  take  into  account  the  equally  striking 
expansion  of  services  and  staff  at  the  municipal  level.  While  looking  at  local  govern- 
ment, it  is  well  to  keep  in  mind  the  point  raised  in  the  second  chapter  of  this  Report: 

85 


The  Ontario  Setting 

that  the  Province  is  directly  responsible  for  municipalities  and  school  boards.  Pro- 
vincial authority  over  local  government  touches  upon  virtually  all  local  activities, 
ranging  from  welfare  administration  to  the  form  and  manner  of  keeping  accounts. 
There  can  be  no  question  that  the  final  responsibility  for  the  level,  cost  and  method 
of  financing  local  services  must  rest  with  the  Province.  Thus  no  survey  of  provincial 
finance  and  growth  could  be  complete  without  simultaneously  taking  local  govern- 
ment into  account, 

21.  The  municipal  picture  is  so  kaleidoscopic  that  it  defies  summary  treatment. 
As  an  indication  of  the  general  situation,  it  may  be  noted  that  in  June  1965, 
seventy-three  Ontario  urban  municipalities  with  populations  over  10,000  employed 
nearly  49,000  persons  with  gross  annual  payrolls  running  well  above  $200  million. 
A  complete  picture  would  have  to  include  the  many  more  employees  hired  by  some 
nine  hundred  other  municipalities,  and  several  thousand  local  public  bodies  such  as 
municipal  utilities  and  school  boards.  Municipal  authorities,  like  the  Province,  have 
had  to  cope  with  the  scientific  and  technological  advances  that  make  new  programs 
feasible,  and  that  create  increased  public  expectations  for  more  and  better  services. 
This  applies  to  sewage  treatment  as  well  as  snow-plowing,  to  firefighting  as  well  as 
the  care  of  the  aged.  Improvements  in  technical  capacity,  as  previously  noted, 
necessitate  a  continuing  drive  to  extend  primary  and  secondary  education,  the  main 
burden  of  which  has  been  borne  by  local  property.  Again,  the  trends  toward 
urbanization  and  the  concentration  of  industry  and  population  create  a  variety  of 
social  and  technical  problems  that  necessitate  governmental  action  and  increased 
public  expenditures. 

PATTERNS  OF  GOVERNMENT  FINANCE 

22.  An  analysis  of  the  expenditure  and  revenue  patterns  of  the  provincal  gov- 
ernment and  local  authorities  can  provide  an  indispensable  outline  of  recent  trends 
in  government  receipts  and  disbursements,  together  with  a  sketch  of  the  manner  in 
which  public  funds  are  allocated.  At  the  same  time,  such  an  analysis  can  reveal  the 
pressure  points  on  our  taxation  system  that  have  given  rise  to  this  inquiry.  Unfor- 
tunately, however,  no  analysis  of  revenues  and  expenditures  is  possible  without  a 
degree  of  arbitrariness  in  the  choice  of  figures.  Data  series  that  are  consistent  over 
time  are,  as  we  shall  have  occasion  to  comment  upon  later  in  this  Report,  all  too 
difficult  to  assemble.  After  a  great  deal  of  work,  we  were  able  to  come  up  with 
time  series  on  general  expenditures  and  revenues,  which  require  brief  explanation. 
General  expenditures  offer  a  tabulation  of  current  and  capital  expenditures  in  the 
year  during  which  spending  took  place.  With  respect  to  capital  expenditures,  this 
means  that  our  figures  purport  to  show  whatever  capital  funds  were  spent  in  any 
given  year,  whether  from  general  revenues  or  from  borrowing.  We  have  scrupu- 
lously attempted  to  omit  allocations  for  debt  repayment,  since  these  would  involve 
double  counting,  but  cannot  vouch  for  100  per  cent  success,  particularly  in  our 
presentation  of  municipal  expenditures.  The  reader  should  note  that  municipalities 
are  obliged  by  law  to  balance  current  expenditures  and  revenues.  From  time  to  | 
time,  this  creates  pressures  to  restrain  current  spending  below  optimum  levels,  and 
induces  a  strong  tendency  for  capital  expenditures  to  fluctuate  in  accordance  with 

86 


Chapter  4:  Paragraphs  21-25 

the  intensity  of  the  restrictions  that  current  revenues  place  on  current  expenditures. 
In  combining  current  and  capital,  our  general  expenditure  figures  are  thus  only  a 
rough  guide  to  municipal  fiscal  trends,  but  they  are  the  best  we  could  assemble 
under  the  circumstances. 

23.  In  using  figures  that  purport  to  measure  general  expenditures  and  revenues, 
we  have  found  it  advisable  to  make  adjustments  for  three  different  types  of  dis- 
tortions which  would  otherwise  all  combine  to  exaggerate  the  changes  that  have 
taken  place.  First,  we  make  a  distinction  between  gross  and  net  expenditures. 
Gross  expenditures  represent  the  total  outlays  of  one  level  of  government  regardless 
of  whether  that  government  is  spending  funds  raised  by  itself  or  funds  secured  by 
transfer  from  the  revenue  system  of  another  level  of  government.  Net  expenditure, 
on  the  other  hand,  is  that  part  of  a  government's  total  spending  that  is  financed 
directly  by  the  level  of  government  in  question.  This  distinction  is  obviously 
important  where,  in  a  multi-level  system  of  government  such  as  ours,  transfers 
between  federal  and  provincial  and  between  provincial  and  municipal  authorities 
constitute  vital  elements  of  public  finance  and  indicate,  for  any  level  of  govern- 
ment, the  gap  between  its  expenditure  commitments  and  the  yield  of  its  own 
revenues  and  borrowing.  Next,  if  comparisons  are  extended  over  a  lengthy  time 
span,  allowance  must  be  m.ade  for  the  changing  value  of  the  dollar  attributable 
to  inflation.  Thus,  our  tabulations  begin  with  unadjusted  absolute  dollar  figures, 
and  are  then  converted  to  constant  dollar  figures.  Finally,  rising  expenditures 
and  revenues,  even  when  rendered  in  constant  dollars,  do  not  allow  for  increases 
in  population.  Thus,  an  additional  and  more  meaningful  calculation  can  be  based 
on  per-capita  figures. 

EXPENDITURE  PATTERNS 

24.  With  these  necessary  preliminary  explanations  out  of  the  way,  we  may 
look  first  at  the  expenditure  side  of  the  ledger.  Chart  4:1  depicts  the  growth  in 
gross  and  net  money  expenditures  for  the  provincial  government  as  well  as  for 
local  governments,  the  latter  divided  between  the  municipalities  and  the  school 
boards.  No  adjustments  have  been  made  for  the  changing  value  of  the  dollar  or 
for  population  increases. 

25.  An  examination  of  Chart  4:1  provides  a  summary  of  the  total  picture. 
Since  the  end  of  the  war,  the  spending  patterns  of  the  three  levels  of  government 
have  shown  a  continuous  increase.  The  reader  should  note,  however,  the  rather 
wide  divergence  between  the  gross  and  net  money  expenditure  figures.  Gross 
money  expenditures  reveal  a  substantially  faster  rate  of  growth  than  net  money 
expenditures.  The  differential  in  the  rate  of  growth  is  accounted  for  by  the 
substantial  jump  in  the  amount  of  grants  made  available  by  the  more  senior  levels 
of  government.  Thus  Chart  4:1  emphatically  underlines  an  eight-fold  increase 
in  the  gross  money  expenditure  of  municipalities  since  1939,  a  ten-fold  increase 
for  the  provincial  government  and  a  remarkable  increase,  apparently  in  excess 
of  fourteen  times  the  1939  level,  for  the  school  boards. 

87 


The  Ontario  Setting 


1600 
1400 

1200 
1000 

800 
600 

400 


O  200 


180 
160 

140 

120 

100 


60 


^     40 


20 


Chart  4:1 
Gross  and  net  money  expenditure.  Province,  municipalities  and  school  boards, 


~PROV.~ 
GROSS 


1600 
1400 
1200 

1000 
800 

600 
400 


200  g 
180  ^ 
160  i 

140 
120 


100 


60 


40 


J L 


I  I  I  I 


1940 


1945 


1950 


1955 


1960     1963 


20 


Source:  Tables  4:1  and  4:2 


88 


\ 


Chapter  4:  Paragraphs  26-30 

26.  This  initial  picture  needs  to  be  refined  by  taking  into  account  the  grants  of 
senior  governments.  Thus  the  net  expenditure  figures  of  school  boards  reveal  a 
sharp  rate  of  growth,  but  one  that  is  nevertheless  substantially  less  rapid  than 
indicated  by  the  gross  data  in  Chart  4:1.  In  particular,  the  more  than  fourteen- 
fold  increase  since  1939  in  the  gross  expenditures  of  school  boards  is  seen  as  less 
than  a  ten-fold  net  increase.  The  net  expenditure  figures  for  the  province  and 
municipalities  display  a  less  extreme  trend,  but  here  the  distinctions  between 
gross  and  net  expenditure  trends  are  less  great  than  for  school  boards.  The  ten-fold 
increase  in  gross  provincial  expenditure  becomes  a  nine-fold  increase  in  net 
expenditure,  and  the  eight-fold  rise  in  gross  municipal  expenditure  is  transformed 
into  a  seven-fold  rise  in  net  expenditure. 

27.  The  index  figures  of  Chart  4:2a  reflect  the  general  trends  observed  with 
respect  to  net  expenditure.  The  use  of  index  numbers  enables  us  to  have  a 
precise  idea  of  the  rate  of  change  in  public  expenditures.  Among  other  things, 
for  example,  indexes  emphasize  the  substantial  curtailment  of  expenditures  by  the 
Province  and  by  the  municipalities  during  the  war  years.  Notably,  school  board 
expenditures  were  never  reduced  by  as  much  as  were  those  of  the  Province  and 
its  municipalities.  Since  1945,  the  expenditures  of  all  three  levels  of  government 
have  been  rising  rapidly  and  continuously. 

28.  Incorporating  an  allowance  for  the  changing  value  of  the  dollar — using  the 
1949  dollar  as  the  base — puts  the  expenditure  trends  depicted  in  Chart  4:2a  in  a 
rather  different  perspective.  From  Chart  4:2b  we  find  that  provincial  government 
expenditures  have  risen  only  a  little  more  than  three  times  their  1939  level  in  real 
terms,  and  those  of  the  municipalities  just  less  than  three  times.  School  board 
expenditures,  though  still  showing  the  largest  proportionate  increase,  nevertheless 
have  increased  less  than  four-fold,  when  measured  in  these  constant  dollar  (real) 
terms  during  the  period. 

29.  Having  now  interpreted  net  government  expenditures  in  real  terms,  we  shall 
make  one  further  adjustment  in  the  original  data,  to  recognize  the  important  factor 
of  population  growth.  Accordingly,  we  measure  the  net  real  outlays  of  each  level 
of  government  in  per-capita  terms,  and  the  result,  as  seen  from  Chart  4:2c,  is  a 
much  more  conservative  picture  of  the  rising  costs  of  government.  Current  net 
real  per-capita  expenditures  for  the  provincial  government  are  not  quite  double 
the  1939  figure;  for  the  municipalities  the  figure  is  only  half  as  much  again  as  in 
1939;  and  school  board  expenditures  show  the  highest  rate  of  increase,  but  are 
still  less  than  double  the  figure  for  1939. 

30.  The  above  trends  concern  net  expenditure  only.  It  may  now  be  desirable 
to  sketch  emergent  trends  in  government  expenditure  not  in  net  terms,  but  rather 
according  to  where  ultimate  spending  is  incurred  by  level  of  government.  This 
is  portrayed  in  Charts  4:3a,  4:3b  and  4:3c,  which  deal  with  gross  provincial 
expenditure  less  any  grants  paid  to  municipalities  and  school  boards,  together 
with  gross  municipal  and  school  spending,  that  is  to  say  including  grants  received 
from  the  Province.  These  charts  respectively  trace  expenditures  in  the  same  terms 

89 


The  Ontario  Setting 


Chart  4:2 

Indexes  of  expenditure:  Province,  municipalities  and  school  boards, 

1939-63. 


1940 
Source:  Table  4:2 


1945 


1950 


1955 


1960  1963 


90 


Chapter  4 :  Paragraph  3 1 


400  — 


-  300 


200 


100 


Chart  4:2b 

- 

Net  real  expenditure.                                                                  ~ 

— 

SCHOOL 
BOARDS       ^^ 

^         >^ROVINCE 

^'^^^^^  _. ..••''municipalities 

- 

— 

^^<^^^^ 

*^^^2A^=5>;;^^i=*' 

1 

1    1    1    1 

1   1    1    1       1    1    1    1       1    1    1    1       1   1    1    1   1 

—  400 


—  300  - 


—  200 


100 


1940         1945 
Source:  Table  4:4 


1950 


1955 


1960 


1963 


300 


200 


100 


Chart  4:2c 

Net  real  per-capita  expenditure.                                                             ~ 

- 

- 

- 

- 

- 

SCHOOL  BOARDS ^           

^^      ^X      ^X^-^PROVINCE  - 

4 

^5:^5. 

s^;.::::;> 

^^^^^""^fT^..... 

<ii^'*''^ 

1       1 

1  1 

1  1  1 

i      III              1       1       1       1             1       1       1       1             1       1       1       1       1 

300 


200 


100 


1940         1945 
Source:  Table  4;5 


1950 


1955 


1960 


1963 


as  Charts  4:2a,  4:2b  and  4:2c,  namely  money,  real,  and  real  per  capita.  The 
principal  ensuing  diflference  is  to  highlight  the  spending  role  of  school  boards  and 
municipalities  as  the  jurisdictions  of  ultimate  disbursement,  by  contrast  to  the 
position  of  the  Province  as  a  major  grant-disbursing  agency.  From  Chart  4:3c, 
real  per-capita  school  board  spending  is  seen  to  be  almost  three  times,  rather  than 
twice  its  1939  level,  while  that  of  the  municipaUties  approaches  twice  its  1939 
level,  exceeding  slightly  the  provincial,  which  in  turn  is  about  one  and  one-half 
times  its  1939  level. 

31.  A  somewhat  different  but  related  perspective  is  provided  in  Chart  4:4. 
Here,  the  net  expenditures  of  provincial  and  local  authorities  on  goods  and 
services  are  related  to  the  estimated  provincial  domestic  product.  From  the 
chart,  we  can  observe  that  combined  government  expenditures  on  goods  and 
services  had  relatively  less  significance  for  the  provincial  economy  during  and 


91 


The  Ontario  Setting 


Chart  4:3 

Government  expenditures  by  level  of  ultimate  spending  responsibility, 

1939-63. 


1500 
1400 
1300 
1200 

1100 

1000 

B  900 

1 

ON 

S  800 
700 
600 
500 
400 
300 
200 
100 
0 


Chart  4:3a 

Indexes  of  money  expenditures  by  level  of  ultimate  spending  responsibility. 

- 

/ 

• 

- 

_ 

/ 

_ 

• 

/ 

« 

/ 

• 

1 
/ 

- 

- 

SCHOOL  BOARDS/ 

# 

/ 

/ 

• 

/ 

_ 

- 

/        MUNICIPALITIES 1 

— 

• 
/ 

- 

- 

- 

— 

/*                      ./^ 

— 

•*             /y 

" 

y        // 

- 

/        // 

- 

/        /'y 

_ 

/      ..••****>r 

- 

y              f     /province 

y    y-?^ — 

— 

- 

— 

y'^y'l^'''^ 

^•^•^l.»»*^ 

1  1 

1  1  1  1     1  1  1  1     1  1  1  1  1  1  1  1  1     1  1  1  1 

1 

1940         1945 
Source:  Table  4:6a 


1950 


1955 


1960 


1963 


1500 

1400 

1300   ! 

1200 

1100 

1000 

900  S 

I 
800  S 

700 

600 

500 

400 

300 

200 

100 

0 


92 


Chapter  4:  Paragraph  31 


500 

400 

Q 
2  300 

II 

?  200 
100 




Chart  4:3b 

- 

Indexes  of  real  expenditures  by  level  of  ultimate  spending  responsibility. 

— 

- 

- 

— 

SCHOOL  BOARDS  /* 

- 

♦            MUNICIPALITIES 

•*^5i 

1      1 

1        1        1       1               1        1        1        1               1        1        1        1        1        1       1        1        1               1        1        1        1        1 

1940 
Source:  Table  4:6b 


1945 


1950 


1955 


1960 


1963 


500 
400 

300   2 

II 

200  2 
100 
0 


400 
300 
200 
100 


Chart  4:3c 
Indexes  of  real  per-capita  expenditures  by  level  of  ultimate  spending  responsibility. 


school  board^.^ 
..—••■*'       municipalities" 
province 


400 
300 
200 
100 


—  o\ 


I 


1940 
Source:   Table  4:6c 

immediately  after  the  war  years  than  in  1939.  Indeed,  the  over-all  1939  position 
was  not  re-established  until  as  late  as  1957.  Thereafter,  combined  public 
expenditures  occupied  a  proportionally  more  important  place,  attaining  in  the 
sixties  approximately  1 1  per  cent  of  the  real  provincial  domestic  product.  Among 
the  net  expenditures  of  the  several  levels  of  government,  those  of  the  Province  not 
only  made  the  more  rapid  recovery  to  the  1939  level,  attaining  it  in  1954,  but  they 
also  accounted  for  proportionately  more  of  the  increase  than  similar  net  local 
expenditures,  which  did  not  recover  their  1939  level  until  1961.  We  already  know 
from  Charts  4:3a,  4:3b  and  4:3c  that  the  inclusion  of  grants  in  the  expenditures 
of  the  level  of  government  ultimately  spending  the  funds  has  the  effect  of  deflating 
provincial  spending,  boosting  the  municipal  rate  of  spending  increase  to  second 
place,  and  accentuating  stiU  further  the  relative  rise  in  school  board  outlays.  We 
restrict  ourselves  to  the  net  expenditure  concept  in  Chart  4:4  only  because  our 

93 


The  Ontario  Setting 


10 


-       \ 


—  \ 


a 
< 

^     5 
u 
u 
a: 

u 


Chart  4:4 

Provincial  and  local  net  expenditure  on  goods  and  services  as  a  percentage 
of  provincial  domestic  product,  1939-63. 


/•'" 


1     — 


\  ^* 


PROVINCIAL 
AND  LOCAL 


I        I        I 


I        I        I        I        I 


1940  1945 

Source:  Table  4:7 


1950 


1955 


1960  1963 


94 


Chapter  4:  Paragraphs  32-34 

prime  concern  is  to  distinguish  the  proportion  of  their  expenditure  programs  that 
provincial  and  local  governments  are  able  to  finance  out  of  their  own  resources 
from  that  for  which  they  are  dependent  upon  transfers  of  funds  from  the  federal 
government. 

32.  The  conclusions  that  may  be  derived  from  the  foregoing  analysis  of  the 
general  expenditure  pattern  of  provincial  and  local  governments  in  Ontario  may 
now  be  quickly  summarized.  Unadjusted  gross  money  figures,  which  show  a 
respective  ten-fold,  eight-fold  and  fourteen-fold  increase  in  provincial,  municipal 
and  school  board  spending,  greatly  exaggerate  the  picture.  This  is  in  part  because 
they  count  government  grants  twice.  Account  may  be  taken  of  grants  by  referring 
either  to  net  government  expenditure,  or  to  government  spending  by  the  level  of 
jurisdiction  ultimately  disbursing  funds.  The  latter  method  shows  that  school 
board  and  municipal  spending  has  increased  at  a  somewhat  faster  rate  than  that 
of  the  Province,  the  former  places  the  Province  ahead  of  the  municipalities. 
When  further  allowance  is  made  for  changes  in  the  value  of  the  dollar  and  popula- 
tion growth,  we  find  that  at  no  level  of  government  has  per-capita  expenditure  more 
than  doubled,  save  for  school  boards  if  their  expenditures  include  grant  receipts. 
Finally,  if  provincial,  municipal  and  school  board  net  real  expenditures  are  com- 
bined and  taken  as  a  percentage  of  provincial  domestic  product,  there  is  no 
dramatic  shift  from  the  1939  situation.  There  has,  in  fact,  been  a  rise  over  the 
whole  period  of  only  2  percentage  points,  that  is  from  approximately  9  to  1 1  per 
cent. 

33.  While  these  conclusions  set  the  combined  provincial  and  local  government 
expenditures  in  proper  perspective,  one  cannot  discount  their  impact  on  govern- 
ment services.  The  significance  of  the  two-fold  increase  in  net  real  expenditure 
per  capita  for  the  various  services  can  be  demonstrated  by  breaking  down  money 
figures  into  their  several  components. 

EXPENDITURE  BY  FUNCTION 

34.  A  functional  classification  of  provincial  government  net  expenditures  is 
presented  in  Charts  4:5a  and  4:5b.  Three  major  areas  of  spending  that  leap 
immediately  to  the  eye  are  education,  health  and  highways.  In  the  two  decades 
following  the  end  of  the  war,  education  and  highways  have  vied  with  one  another 
in  claiming  the  major  share  of  the  provincial  budget,  a  rise  in  the  proportion 
secured  by  one  seeming  to  produce  reductions  in  the  share  allocated  to  the  other. 
In  1945,  over  one-third  of  the  budget  was  devoted  to  these  two  functions;  twenty 
years  later  they  together  accounted  for  considerably  more  than  half  the  budget. 
Education  alone,  if  expenditures  on  universities  are  included,  has  come  to  account 
for  more  than  one-third  of  the  Province's  net  ordinary  expenditures.  Highways, 
after  holding  first  place  uninterruptedly  from  1947  to  1961,  are  now  entrenched 
in  second,  accounting  for  between  one-quarter  and  one-fifth  of  provincial  expendi- 
ture. Among  the  remaining  major  functions,  health,  under  the  impetus  of  provincial 
contributions  to  hospital  and  medical  insurance,  has  moved  firmly  into  third 
place,  a  position  it  has  held  since  1958,  with  between  10  and  15  per  cent  of  recent 

95 


The  Ontario  Setting 


40 


35 


30 


25 

ui 
O 
< 

Z 

UJ 

y    20 

UJ 


10 


Chart  4:5a 

Percentage  analysis  of  net  expenditure  for  major  provincial 

functions,  fiscal  years  ending  March  31,  1945-64. 


EDUCATION 


40 


35 


30 


25 

UJ 

a 
< 

H 
Z 

UJ 

20    ^ 

ID 


HEALTH 
/        \ 


V. 


.•'public  debt 


\ 


I    I    I    I    I    I    I    I 


I    I    I    I 


I    I    I 


1945  1950 

Source:   Table  4:9 


1955 


1960 


1964 


96 


Chapter  4:  Charts  4:5a-4:5b 


10 


Chart  4:5b 

Percentage  analysis  of  net  expenditure  for  other  provincial 
functions,  fiscal  years  ending  March  31,  1945-64. 


•                  .•• 

/\ 

*           ,* 

•    » 

*....•* 

• 

/  \ 

NATURAL 
RESOURCES 

', 

/ 

• 

*W 

J 

• 

/    ' 

V 

I L 


I     I     I     I 


I     I     I     I     I 


1945  1950 

Source:  Table  4:9 


1955 


1960 


1964 


10 


5    < 


97 


The  Ontario  Setting 

budgets  allocated  to  it.  The  proportion  of  the  budget  absorbed  by  interest  on  the 
public  debt  has  dropped  over  a  period  of  twenty  years  from  first  place  to  a  low 
fourth  place.  Despite  the  fact  that  welfare  currently  occupies  fifth  place  in  the 
order  of  spending,  its  proportional  share  of  the  budget  has  declined  from  roughly 
10  per  cent  to  5  per  cent  of  the  total. 

35.  Although  there  has  been  a  steady  increase  in  the  absolute  sums  devoted  to 
the  other  segments  of  government  expenditure,  the  proportion  of  the  total  each 
enjoys  has  tended  to  decline  or  remain  relatively  static.  From  Chart  4:5b,  we 
observe  that  the  traditional  functions  of  law  enforcement  and  reform  have  enjoyed 
a  modest  share  of  the  budget,  ranging  between  3.5  and  4.5  per  cent  of  the  total. 
Similarly,  municipal  affairs  spending  has  averaged  about  3.5  per  cent;  that  for 
pubUc  works  has  been  less  stable,  ranging  from  a  high  of  7.5  to  a  low  of  1  per 
cent  and  now  standing  at  roughly  3.5  per  cent.  Natural  resources,  for  their  part, 
have  experienced  a  fairly  steady  decline  in  their  relative  share  of  the  budget. 

36.  Shifting  to  the  local  scene,  we  present  in  Charts  4:6a  and  4:6b  two 
closely  related  sketches  of  local  spending  by  function.  Chart  4:6a  depicts  the 
relative  position  of  major  local  functions  as  a  percentage  of  net  expenditure; 
Chart  4:6b  traces  relative  position  as  a  percentage  of  gross  expenditure.  Read 
Together,  the  two  charts  enable  the  reader  to  grasp  the  impact  of  provincial  grants 
on  local  spending  responsibilities.  Whether  as  a  proportion  of  net  or  gross  local 
expenditure,  education  and  roads  persistently  tower  above  all  others.  Since  the 
early  fifties,  these  two  together  have  generally  accounted  for  50  per  cent  or  more 
of  net  local  expenditures,  and  for  60  per  cent  or  more  of  gross  expenditure.  That 
these  two  functions  constitute  a  relatively  larger  share  of  gross  than  of  net 
expenditure  is  testimony  to  the  much  larger  provincial  grant  funds  allocated  to 
these  purposes  than  to  others.  Of  the  remaining  functions,  all  but  health  and 
welfare,  where  grant  funds  also  concentrate,  constitute  a  smaller  share  of  gross 
than  of  net  expenditure. 

37.  In  general,  it  can  be  said  that  the  relative  shares  of  net  expenditure 
allocated  to  each  of  the  major  local  functions  have  tended  to  remain  rather  more 
stable  than  either  the  relative  shares  of  gross  expenditure  or,  for  that  matter,  the 
corresponding  items  in  the  provincial  budget.  This,  of  course,  is  because  provincial 
grants  change  from  time  to  time  in  accordance  with  new  poHcy  commitments, 
with  consequent  time  lags  and  fluctuations  that  are  reflected,  for  example,  in  the 
noticeably  wider  swing  of  the  education  line  in  Chart  4:6b  than  in  Chart  4:6a. 
The  relative  stability  of  proportional  commitments  in  terms  of  local  net  expendi- 
ture underlines  the  residual  nature  of  the  responsibilities  municipalities  and  school 
boards  shoulder  as  the  level  of  government  closest  to  the  people. 

COMPARISON  WITH  OTHER  PROVINCES 

38.  Before  turning  our  attention  to  the  revenue  sources  from  which  govern- 
ments have  sought  to  meet  the  rising  expenditures  described  above,  it  will  be 
useful  to  place  Ontario's  spending  pattern  in  a  broader,  national  perspective. 
Chart  4:7  enables  us  to  relate  increasing  provincial  and  local  expenditure  to  the 

98 


Chapter  4:  Paragraphs  35-38 


50 


45 


40 


35 


30 


"J    25 

< 

l- 
z. 

LL) 
U 
Oi 
O! 

0-    20 


15 


10 


Chart  4:6a 

Percentage  analysis  of  net  local  expenditure  by  function, 
1951-63. 


/^. 


V-  — " 


.    EDUCATION 


.- "S 


V  H1GHWAYS^__. 


MISCELLANEOUS 


_,  .SANITATION   AND 

"*       WASTE  REMOVAL 


DEBT 


50 


45 


40 


35 


30 


25    g 

Z 

Ul 

u 
a: 

20    S 


10 


1951  1953 

Source:  Table  4:11 


1955 


1957 


1959 


1961 


1963 


99 


The  Ontario  Setting 


50 


45 


40 


35 


30 


25 


< 

i- 
z 
tu 

Qi    20 

UJ 


15 


10 


Chart  4:6b 

Percentage  analysis  of  gross  local  expenditure  by  function, 
1952-63. 


\ 


EDUCATION 


/^^X/ 


/     HIGHWAYS 


^^/ 


••.SANITATION  AND 
/  \  WASTE  REMOVAL 


1952 
Source:  Table  4:13 


1954 


1956 


1958 


1960 


1962      1963 


100 


Chapter  4:  Charts  4:6b-4:7 


20 


16 


10 


Chart  4:7 

Combined  provincial  and  local  expenditure  as  a  percentage  of 

gross  domestic  product  in  Ontario  and  in  rest  of  Canada, 

1945-62. 


REST  OF 
CANADA 


I        I        I        I        I 


20 


18 


1945  1950 

Source:  Table  4:14 


1955 


1960     1962 


101 


The  Ontario  Setting 


PERCENTAGE 


3-§ 
■■B  " 
u  in 

c  > 

H       U    O 


<    ^ 


c^ 


o  o 

—  o 

■o.S 

c  _ 

c 


9 


PERCENTAGE 


102 


Chapter  4:  Paragraphs  39-42 

growing  productivity  of  the  country.  It  is  apparent  from  the  chart  that  spending 
by  all  Canadian  provinces  and  local  authorities  has  increasingly  outpaced  the 
rate  of  growth  in  provincial  domestic  product.  In  Ontario,  combined  provincial 
and  local  net  general  expenditures,  taken  as  a  percentage  of  provincial  domestic 
product,  have  risen  almost  without  remission  from  5.8  per  cent  in  1945  to  14.9 
percent  in  1962. 

39.  A  related  point  is  that  the  combined  provincial  and  local  net  general 
expenditures  of  the  Province  of  Ontario  have  consistently  represented  a  lower 
proportion  of  the  provincial  domestic  product  than  the  average  for  all  other 
provinces  combined.  This  differential  is  attributable  to  the  high  productivity  of  the 
Province  of  Ontario,  whose  domestic  product  represents  approximately  40  per 
cent  of  the  total  production  of  all  Canadian  provinces.  Nevertheless,  it  should  be 
noted  that  Ontario's  net  general  expenditures  have  apparently  been  growing  at  a 
slightly  more  rapid  rate  than  the  combined  expenditures  of  the  other  provinces. 

40.  Chart  4:8  provides  another  measure  of  Ontario's  position  relative  to  that 
of  the  other  provinces.  In  so  far  as  total  personal  income  can  be  used  as  a  measure 
of  the  capacity  of  the  public  to  sustain  a  particular  level  of  government  spending, 
we  may  note  two  points  that  emerge  from  this  chart.  First,  all  provinces,  Ontario 
not  excepted,  have  been  raising  their  governmental  expenditures  at  a  rate  faster 
than  the  growth  of  total  personal  incomes  within  their  respective  jurisdictions. 
However,  both  in  1952  and  in  1962,  only  Manitoba's  net  general  government 
expenditure  taken  as  a  percentage  of  personal  income  was  lower  than  Ontario's. 

41.  It  would  thus  appear  that  government  expenditure  in  all  provinces  has 
been  increasing  at  a  rate  faster  than  the  growth  rate  of  either  provincial  domestic 
product  or  total  personal  incomes.  However,  the  relatively  larger  domestic  product 
and  higher  personal  incomes  in  Ontario  have  meant  that  government  expenditure 
as  a  percentage  of  these  two  factors  has  not  been  as  high  as  in  all  other  provinces 
taken  together.  Over  against  this  conclusion  we  must  set  out  the  fact,  which  may 
be  verified  in  the  appendix  (Table  4:16),  that  the  per-capita  net  general  expenditure 
in  Ontario  is  the  third  highest  in  Canada,  exceeded  only  by  Alberta  and  British 
Columbia. 

REVENUE  PATTERNS 

42.  Governments,  of  course,  are  not  only  spenders  but,  as  all  legislators  are 
aware,  must  concern  themselves  with  finding  "ways  and  means"  to  finance  their 
expenditure  programs.  Consequently,  we  now  turn  to  the  revenue  sources — both 
provincial  and  local — that  have  had  to  be  tapped  to  keep  pace  with  the  mounting 
costs  of  government  in  Ontario.  For  the  Province  there  are  hundreds  of  these 
revenue  sources,  ranging  from  innumerable  minor  items  such  as  fees  charged  for 
the  registration  of  jockeys,  the  licensing  of  elevators  and  the  sale  of  publications 
to  a  few  major  ones  such  as  taxes  on  income  and  on  various  classes  of  expenditure. 
For  their  part,  municipalities  and  school  boards  enjoy  only  one  major  revenue 
source,  the  property  tax,  supplemented  for  municipalities  by  a  host  of  minor 
revenues. 

103 


The  Ontario  Setting 


2000 

1800 
1600 
1400 
1200 

1000 
800 

600 


400 


200 
I  180 
I  ISO 
^     140 

120 

100 
80 


60 


40 


20 


Chart  4:9 


Gross  and  net  revenue,  Province,  municipalities  and  school  boards, 
1939-63. 


2000 
1800 
1600 
1400 
1200 

tlOOO 
800 

600 


400 


200 
180 
160 

140 

120 

100 
80 

60 


40 


J L 


I     I     I 


I     I 


20 


1940  1945 

Source:   Tables  4:20  and  4:21 


1950 


1955 


1960 


1963 


104 


Chapter  4:  Charts  4:9-4: 10a 


Chart  4:10 

Indexes  of  revenue;  Province,  municipalities  and  school  boards, 
1939-63. 


1300 


1200 


1100 


1000 


900 


800 


700 


600 


500 


400 


300 


200 


100 


Chart  4:10a 
Net  money  revenue. 


PROVINCE       • 
/ 


/         SCHOOL  BOARDS 


/ 


MUNICIPALITIES 


1300 


1200 


1100 


1000 


900 


800 


700 


600 


500 


400 


300 


200 


—  .'^ 


■J&*MM^£*^^^ 


I  I  I  I  I  I  1  I  I  I  I  I  I \ L_L 


I  I  I  I 


100 


1940         1945 
Source:  Table  4:21 


1950 


1955 


1960     1963 


105 


The  Ontario  Setting 

600 


500 


400 


Jl    300 


200 


100 


Chart  4:10b 
Net  real  revenue. 


PROVINCE  • 


SCHOOL  BOARDS 


MUNICIPALITIES 


I        I        I 


I        I        I        I        I        I        I        I 


600 


500 


400 


300 


200 


100 


1940  1945 

Source:   Table  4:22 


1950 


1955 


1960 


1963 


bUU 


500 


400 


300 


200 


100 


Chart  4:10c 
Net  real  revenue  per  capita. 


PROVINCE,  X 

SCHOOL  BOARDS 


»M ** 


I         I         I         I 


I         I         I         I 


-L_L 


MUNICIPALITIES 


I   I   I   I   I 


600 


500 


400 


300 


200 


100 


1940 
Source:  4:23 


1945 


1950 


1955 


1960 


1963 


43.  Chart  4:9  reveals  that  the  gross  revenue  of  the  Province,  which  reflects 
the  yield  from  the  provincial  revenue  system  plus  transfers  of  federal  funds,  has 
increased  thirteen-fold  since  1939.  The  growing  divergence  that  the  chart  reveals 
between  gross  and  net  provincial  revenue  attests  the  enhanced  importance  of 
federal  transfer  payments.  Provincial  net  revenue,  a  measure  that  excludes  federal 
transfers,  has  multiplied  twelve-fold  over  the  same  period.    This  appreciable  in- 

106 


Chapter  4:  Paragraphs  43-47 

crease  underlines  the  point  that,  despite  constitutional  limitations  to  use  only 
"direct  taxation  within  the  Province",  flexible  interpretations  and  official  ingenuity 
have  managed  to  devise  a  variety  of  taxes  designed  to  generate  revenues  sufficient 
to  meet  expenditure  programs. 

44.  On  the  municipal  and  school  front,  Chart  4:9  reveals  that  between  1939 
and  1963  gross  money  revenue  of  municipalities  increased  almost  six-fold,  while 
school  board  revenue  increased  more  than  ten-fold.  However,  because  of  extensive 
reliance  on  grants  from  the  Province,  municipal  and  school  net  revenues  show  a 
much  less  marked  increase:  less  than  a  five-fold  rise  for  municipalities  and  only 
a  seven-fold  rise  for  the  school  boards. 

45.  The  rate  at  which  provincial,  municipal  and  school  revenues  have  been 
increasing  is  depicted  in  Charts  4:10a,  4:10b  and  4:10c,  which  indicate  indexes 
of  net  money  revenue,  net  real  revenue  and  net  real  revenue  per  capita.  As  with 
expenditures,  taking  account  of  changing  dollar  values  and  population  growth 
sharply  reduces  the  upward  trend  of  net  revenue  when  reported  in  simple  money 
terms.  From  Chart  4:10c,  it  will  be  observed  that  on  a  net  real  per-capita  basis, 
provincial  revenue  is  barely  250  per  cent  of  its  1939  level,  and  did  not  double  its 
1939  mark  until  1961.  Municipal  revenue,  meanwhile,  actually  experienced  a 
substantial  relative  decline  after  1939,  returning  to  the  1939  level  only  as  recently 
as  1961.  School  board  revenue,  for  its  part,  displayed  an  even  more  marked 
decline  but  recovered  its  1939  position  in  1956  and  has  now  expanded  to  nearly 
half  as  much  again  as  the  1939  mark. 

SOURCES  OF  REVENUE 

46.  Turning  now  to  the  major  classes  of  provincial  revenue,  we  find  from 
Chart  4:11a  that  expenditure  taxes  have  persistently  dominated  the  picture,  never 
falling  below  40  per  cent  of  net  ordinary  revenue,  and  on  occasion  approaching 
or  even  passing  the  50  per  cent  mark.  Taxes  on  personal  and  corporate  income, 
partly  under  the  impetus  of  increasingly  favourable  federal-provincial  arrangements, 
have  consolidated  an  ever  firmer  grip  on  second  place.  The  introduction  of  the 
retail  sales  tax  barely  depressed  their  1961  peak  of  41  per  cent,  reducing  it  to 
between  35  and  38  per  cent.  Wealth  taxes  in  the  form  of  death  duties  are 
a  poor  third.  They  exhibit  a  pattern  of  steady  decline  in  relative  importance, 
and  have  hovered  at  or  slightly  below  5  per  cent  of  net  ordinary  revenue  since 
1959.  Natural  resource  revenues,  recently  in  the  order  of  3.5  per  cent  of  the  total, 
stand  an  unimpressive  fourth.  The  host  of  miscellaneous  provincial  revenues 
tend  to  fluctuate  in  the  10  to  15  per  cent  range,  before  dipping  to  roughly  8  per 
cent  after  1962. 

47.  Chart  4:11b  offers  a  detailed  look  at  the  principal  components  of 
expenditure-based  provincial  revenues.  These,  of  course,  are  the  retail  sales  tax, 
introduced  in  1961,  and  the  much  older  gasoline  tax,  motor  vehicle  permits  and 
Liquor  Control  Board  profit.  The  retail  sales  tax  rivalled  the  gasoline  tax  in 
importance  from  the  moment  of  its  inception,  and  will  achieve  unchallenged 
pre-eminence  at  roughly  22  per  cent  of  total  revenue  in  the  wake  of  the  1966 

107 


The  Ontario  Setting 

rate  increase.  As  is  to  be  expected,  gasoline  tax,  liquor  and  motor  vehicle  revenues 
all  declined  in  relative  importance  after  the  introduction  of  the  sales  tax,  and  now 
represent  approximately  15,  8  and  5  per  cent  of  ordinary  revenue  respectively. 
The  reader  will  observe  that,  generally  speaking,  a  rough  1:2  ratio  between  liquor 
and  gasoline  tax  revenues  has  been  sustained. 

48.  With  respect  to  provincial  taxes  on  personal  and  corporate  income,  second 
in  importance  only  to  the  expenditure-based  revenues,  it  should  be  noted  that 
during  the  war  years,  the  provinces  surrendered  their  taxing  jurisdiction  to  Ottawa 
in  return  for  unconditional  payments,  which  are  included  in  Chart  4:11a.  Follow- 
ing the  return  of  peace,  the  Province  of  Ontario  refused  to  sign  the  1947  tax-rental 
agreements.  Throughout  the  ensuing  five-year  period,  Ontario  did  not  collect  any 
provincial  personal  income  tax,  but  did  impose  a  7  per  cent  tax  on  corporation 
income.  The  Province  subsequently  decided  to  adhere  to  the  1952  tax-rental 
agreements,  and  for  the  following  five  years  the  category  of  personal  and  corporate 
income  taxes  shown  in  Chart  4:11a  combines  rental  revenues  paid  in  lieu  of  tax 
with  grants  received  under  the  escalator  clause.  Ontario  reimposed  its  own 
corporation  income  tax  in  1957,  and  has  since  derived  personal  income  tax 
revenue  which  the  federal  government  rebates  to  its  taxpayers  under  the  abatement 
provisions  of  the  tax-sharing  and  fiscal  arrangements. 

49.  As  previously  noted,  the  Province  of  Ontario  receives  substantial  transfer 
payments  from  the  federal  government.  A  portion  of  these — moneys  collected  by 
Ottawa  under  various  tax  agreements — have  been  included  in  the  ordinary  revenues 
of  the  Province  examined  in  Chart  4:11a,  because  federal  tax  collectors  act  as 
agents  of  the  Province  and,  since  1962,  have  operated  under  the  authority  of  a 
provincial  statute.  Also  included  in  ordinary  provincial  revenue  are  the  Province's 
25  per  cent  share  of  the  federal  estate  tax,  an  additional  amount  of  sHghtly  over 
$1  million  representing  the  provincial  share  of  federal  income  tax  collected  from 
privately  owned  public  utility  corporations,  and  the  fixed  annual  statutory  subsidies 
of  about  $5  million  granted  at  the  time  of  Confederation.  Much  larger  than  any 
of  these  are  the  federal  transfers  made  under  conditional  grant  and  shared-cost 
programs.  They  amounted  to  $282  million  in  1963-64  and  are  expected  to  be  in 
the  neighbourhood  of  $350  million  in  1966-67,  rivalling  provincial  revenue  from 
the  personal  income  tax.  These  transfers  are  excluded  from  ordinary  revenue,  but 
their  existence  is  attested  by  the  gap  between  gross  and  net  provincial  revenues. 

50.  One  major  source  of  provincial  revenue  that  has  not  been  mentioned  thus 
far  because  it  is  not  entered  in  the  Public  Accounts  is  the  hospital  premium  levied 
by  the  Ontario  Hospital  Services  Commission.  The  premium,  which  may  be  thought 
of  either  as  a  tax  or  as  a  service  charge,  currently  raises  about  $157  million 
annually.  No  broad  survey  of  government  revenue  can  overlook  this  important 
though  somewhat  isolated  source  of  funds  that  has  the  merit  of  growing  steadily 
with  the  expansion  of  population,  and  responding  immediately  and  predictably  to 
any  administered  alteration  in  the  size  of  premiums. 

108 


Chapter  4:  Paragraphs  48-50 


55 


50 


45 


40 


35 


Chart  4:11a 

Percentage  analysis  of  major  classes  of  ordinary  provincial  revenue, 
1939-67. 


A 


v^\ 


/  \ 


\         EXPENDITURE-BASED  / 

REVENUES  X 

*  .*  \ * 


A/ 


/\ 


f  V 

f    PERSONAL  INCOME  AND 


^^^^ 


J' 


CORPORATE  TAXES 


55 


50 


45 


40 


35 


1940  1945 

Source:  Table  4:18 


1950 


1955 


1960 


1965     1967 


109 


The  Ontario  Setting 


55 


50 


45 


40 


35 


UJ 

!^   30 

H 

z 

U 
0£ 
U 

CL, 

25 


Chart  4:11b 
Percentage  analysis  of  principal  components  of  expenditure-based  provincial  revenues, 

1939-67. 


20     — 


15 


10 


/\ 


1— / 

* 

/ 
/ 


;   V. 


/gasoline  tax  V* 


*  *  L.C.B.O.    • 


>J 


**•«••      \ 


55 


50 


45 


40 


35 


30  ^ 

H 
Z 

u 
u 
u. 
u 

a. 
25 


20 


RETAIL 
'SALES   TAX 


-/' 


\  MOTOR  VEHICLE  /         \  ^..^ 

jm.^,^ PERMITS  AND  LICENCES/  ^— -^^*^, 


I   I   I   I  I   I   I   I 


I    I    I    I    I    I    I   I 


1940  1945 

Source:  Table  4:18 


1950 


1955 


1960 


1965     1967 


110 


Chapter  4:  Charts  4:llb-4-13 


100 
90 
80 
70 


w   60 

O 

< 

z   50 

m 
u 
oi 

S   40 


Chart  4:12 

Percentage  analysis  of  gross  municipal  revenues, 
1939-63. 


\--s 


TOTAL  MUNICIPAL  TAX  LEVY 


TOTAL  GRANTS  _-*— 


/ 


OTHER  REVENUES 


I       I       I       I 


I       I       I 


I       I       I       I       1       I 


1940  1945 

Source:  Table  4:24 


1950 


1955 


1960  1963 


100 
90 
80 
70 


60  uj 
o 
< 

50    § 

u 

Oi 

40    0- 


30 

20 

10 

0 


100   I — 


90 


70 


ud 

60 

a 

< 

t- 

7. 

Wl 

UJ 

U 

Bi 

0^ 

40 

30 


20 


Chart  4:13 
Percentage  analysis  of  gross  school  board  revenues, 
1939-63. 


TOTAL  GRANTS 


TOTAL  SCHOOL  TAX  LEVY 

y" — ^'' 


\---^--._    - 


/^ 


J_L 


■     III 


'■1  • -I.  ■■  ]♦••'!      V 


r-i.-r 


OTHER  REVENUES 


I    I    I 


1940  1945 

Source:  Table  4:25 


1950 


1955 


1960 


100 
90 
80 
70 


60  UJ 
a 
< 

50    z 

u 
en 

An      U-' 

40    a. 


30 
20 
10 

0 


1963 


111 


The  Ontario  Setting 

51.  There  remains  for  brief  consideration  a  breakdown  of  municipal  and 
school  revenues.  Charts  4:12  and  4:13  indicate  that  the  major  source  of  gross 
revenue  for  both  municipalities  and  school  boards  has  been  the  real  property  tax. 
For  the  municipalities,  this  source  has  in  the  past  provided  between  75  and  80 
per  cent  of  the  total,  but  has  more  recently  declined  to  about  64  per  cent.  Revenues 
from  sundry  fees,  fines  and  licences  have  ranged  between  10  and  15  per  cent  of 
the  total,  but  in  recent  years  have  remained  steady  at  somewhat  less  than  10  per 
cent  of  all  revenue.  Clearly,  the  relative  decline  in  contributions  from  local 
sources  has  necessitated  a  steady,  substantial  increase  in  the  transfer  of  funds  from 
the  Province.  The  result  has  been  that  grants  from  senior  levels  of  government 
now  account  for  more  than  one-quarter  of  the  gross  revenues  of  the  municipalities. 

52.  Chart  4:13  reveals  that  school  board  revenues  have  followed  municipal 
revenue  patterns  in  somewhat  parallel  fashion.  The  property  tax  has  dominated 
the  sources  of  school  board  revenue,  although  it  has  always  provided  a  lower 
proportion  of  school  than  of  municipal  revenue,  seldom  rising  above  two-thirds 
of  the  total  and  in  recent  years  dropping  to  about  57  per  cent.  At  the  same  time, 
there  has  been  a  more  significant  decline  in  revenues  from  other  local  sources;  in 
1939  they  accounted  for  17.5  per  cent  of  total  revenues  and  have  now  dropped 
below  4  per  cent  of  the  total.  These  particular  revenues  are  composed  in  large 
part  of  tuition  fees  paid  to  school  boards  by  other  local  authorities,  including  other 
school  boards.^  Their  decline  can  be  attributed  in  no  small  measure  to  the  strides 
that  have  been  made  in  consolidating  local  school  organization. 

53.  The  gap  produced  by  the  proportional  decline  in  school  revenue  from 
local  tax  and  other  sources  has  had  to  be  filled,  even  more  than  has  been  true 
for  the  municipalities,  by  grants  from  the  Province.  Their  contribution  to  school 
board  revenues,  always  proportionally  more  than  their  contribution  to  municipal 
resources,  hovers  around  40  per  cent  of  the  total. 

54.  As  a  final  note,  it  is  interesting  to  observe  that  despite  the  necessity  for 
continuously  rising  levels  of  government  revenue  to  further  the  provision  of  a 
constantly  expanding  range  of  public  services,  the  combined  real  net  revenues  of 
provincial  and  local  authorities  in  Ontario  in  1963  represented  no  greater  propor- 
tion of  the  value  of  provincial  domestic  product  than  in  1939.  (See  Chart  4:14.) 
This  should  nevertheless  not  obscure  the  fact  that  during  World  War  II  the  share 
of  annual  real  production  claimed  by  these  governments  declined  sharply,  to  rise 
again  strikingly  after  1945.  It  appears  quite  clear  that  if  the  public  continues  to 
demand  more  and  more  services  from  government — and  one  can  scarcely  doubt 
that  it  will — the  financial  capacity  of  government  must  be  correspondingly  increased. 
The  burden  will  obviously  be  least  under  conditions  of  sustained  economic  growth. 

55.  Throughout  the  foregoing  analysis  we  have  concentrated  on  the  ordinary 
revenue  and  expenditure  patterns  of  government.   A  portion  of  the  costs  of  capital 


'To  the  extent  that  fees  are  paid  by  other  boards,  an  inevitable  degree  of  double 
counting  creeps  into  our  figures,  since  tuition  fees  that  are  paid  by  school  boards  are 
financed  through  property  taxation,  and  thus  appear  once  as  property  tax  revenues 
of  fee-paying  boards  and  again  as  tuition  revenue  of  recipient  boards. 

112 


Chapter  4:  Paragraphs  51-55 


o 
<    fi 

Z 

u 
u 


Chart  4;  14 

Provincial,  municipal  and  school  board  net  revenues  as  a  percentage  of 
provincial  domestic  product,  1939-63. 


SCHOOL  BOARD 


'S^       ^ 


I      I      I      I 


I      I      I      I      I      I      1      I      I      I      I      I      I 


C 

6     H 
Z 

UJ 

U 
a: 

UJ 


1940  1945 

Source:  Table  4:26 


1950 


1955 


1960  1963 


113 


The  Ontario  Setting 


o 

S 

$ 

z 

o 

>. 

Uj 

S 

^ 

^ 

H 

o 

PQ 

O. 

U 

•o 

Q 

u 

o 

O 

_u 

OQ 

' — ' 

D 

Pu 

1    i>i 

^ 

.-So 

q 

r4 

00 

r^ 

SS 

d 

n 

►~i 

"a 

e3 

00 

(7\ 

d 

S 

00 

<s 

< 

< 

^ 

<s 

t 

Z 

1     1>) 

00 

."2  b 

'^ 

00 

r~; 

bj 

S^ 

■* 

•<t 

d 

r^ 

0-s 

•^ 

2  § 
Co 

o 

en 

o 

d 

CO 

^1 

*0 

o 

^ 

< 

< 

3; 

-< 

-< 

;^ 

X 

~»( 

1  '^ 

."2  b 

^ 
^ 

■<t 

(S 

?l 

2   0\ 

>n 

VO 

d 

00 

•2-- 

"I 

53  S 

<S 

00 

o 

q 

^:5 

Wg 

rj 

CO 

d 

■*' 

=r  c 

rp  as 

^ 

CT\ 

'~J 

< 

< 

»5 
to 

r^ 

m 

Z 

z 

*X3 

c^ 

^ 

^_, 

^ 

•2 

il 

"0 

q 

d 

00 

C/3 

13 

2 

S2; 

'"' 

]<j 

c 
O 

o 

d 

q 

d 

o 
<> 

1 

'"^ 

o 

•5 

^ 

^o 

^ 

0 

•o 

>o 

q 

•<t 

VO 

o 

i 

3; 

•^f 

1^ 

d 

9 

r»% 

1 

1 

2 
o. 

a 

o 

1 

1 

i 

a 

4) 

1 

•^ 

§ 

Ih 

is 

4> 

1 

T3 

2 

o 
>■ 

c 

3 
O 
o 

"eS 

13 

o 

< 

.a 

1 

1 

o 

O 

O 

3 

u 

O 

o 

PL. 

Ck 

o. 

*■ 

v^ 

^ 

O 

T3 

•c 

a 

CO 

V3 

_c 

_c 

O 

t/) 

cn 

p 

O 

4_» 

«^ 

u 

u 

u 

u 

<1> 

o 

o 

z 

Z 

y 

114 


Chapter  4:  Paragraphs  56-58 

programs  is  regularly  carried  on  the  ordinary  budget  but  over  the  years  govern- 
ments have  had  to  borrow  in  order  to  meet  growing  needs  for  capital  expenditures. 
It  is  therefore  appropriate  that  in  concluding  this  historical  survey,  we  should 
turn  to  the  main  characteristics  of  the  debt  structure  that  has  been  built  up  in 
response  to  this  residual  but  important  segment  of  governmental  operations. 

DEBT  PATTERNS 

56.  In  the  foregoing  sections,  we  have  tried  to  outline  the  main  trends  in 
provincial,  municipal  and  school  board  general  expenditures  and  revenues  in 
Ontario  since  1939,  and  we  have  measured  these  expenditures  and  revenues  in 
a  number  of  ways  that  appear  to  us  useful.  If,  for  example,  the  reader  will  compare 
Charts  4:2c  and  4:10c,  he  will  find  that,  except  for  the  experience  of  the  school 
board  during  World  War  II,  and  of  the  Province  in  occasional  post-war  years,  the 
net  real  per-capita  expenditures  of  the  three  levels  of  government  with  which  we 
are  concerned  have  at  almost  all  times  exceeded  their  net  real  per-capita  revenues. 
Indeed,  an  examination  of  other  appropriate  charts  in  this  chapter  will  indicate 
that,  as  we  have  measured  it,  an  excess  of  expenditure  over  revenue  has  been 
persistent  at  all  levels  of  government,  regardless  of  the  particular  measurement 
applied.  The  result,  particularly  since  the  end  of  the  war,  has  been  a  continuous 
growth  in  government  debt,  a  summary  of  which  is  provided  in  Charts  4:15 
and  4:16. 

57.  Among  the  ratios  frequently  employed  to  obtain  a  useful  if  rough  indica- 
tion of  the  burden  of  public  debt  are  those  of  gross  debt/provincial  domestic 
product,  gross  debt/provincial  personal  income,  net  interest  costs/provincial 
domestic  product,  and  net  interest  costs/ordinary  revenue.  When  apphed  to  the 
post-war  public  debt  of  provincial  and  local  governments  in  Ontario,  all  of  these 
ratios  indicate  much  the  same  pattern  of  debt  behaviour.  The  Table  suggests  that 
the  burden  of  Ontario  government  debt  declined  modestly  from  the  end  of  World 
War  II  to  the  early  1950's,  and  then  rose  until,  by  the  mid-sixties,  the  approximate 
conditions  of  1945  were  restored.  It  should  be  noted,  however,  that  the  proportion 
of  provincial  ordinary  revenues  required  for  servicing  this  debt  has  decUned 
greatly,  being  in  recent  years  less  than  half  that  of  1945.  By  contrast,  the  post-war 
burden  of  local  (municipal  and  school  board)  debt  has  increased  sharply.  For 
the  municipaUties,  the  burden  appears  to  have  remained  relatively  stable  until  the 
early  1950's  and  then  to  have  more  than  doubled  by  the  mid-sixties.  Even  more 
striking  has  been  the  continuous  rise  in  school  board  debt  throughout  the  post-war 
years,  with  a  resulting  four-fold  increase  in  debt  burden  during  that  period  of  two 
decades. 

58.  We  now  proceed  to  illustrate  in  greater  detail  the  trend  of  Ontario's 
indebtedness  in  terms  of  its  net  direct  capital  debt,  a  measurement  particularly 
appropriate  in  any  discussion  of  the  "burden"  of  public  borrowing.  This  magnitude 
represents  the  total  of  the  Province's  bonded  debt  (less  accumulated  sinking  fund), 
plus  its  unfunded  Habilities,  less  the  total  of  provincial  revenue-producing  and 
realizable  assets — the  latter  being  deemed  to  be  self-sustaining.   Net  direct  capital 

115 


The  Ontario  Setting 

debt  therefore  represents  the  aggregate  of  provincial  borrowing  that  must  be 
serviced  by  the  taxpayers  of  the  province,  and  when  it  is  related  to  some  appropri- 
ate variable  such  as  provincial  domestic  product,  the  resulting  ratio  provides  a 
measure  of  the  burden  of  debt. 

59.  It  is  interesting  to  note  that  the  persistent  upward  trend  in  Ontario's  net 
capital  debt  since  early  in  this  century  appears  to  display  no  marked  cychcal 
pattern;  debt  has  grown  apace  both  in  prosperity  and  depression.  Thus,  the  periods 
of  most  rapid  debt  expansion  have  been : 

(1)  during  the  early  1920's,  when  the  need  for  large-scale  investment  in  social 
capital  brought  a  doubling  of  the  debt  within  five  years; 

(2)  during  the  mid-1930's,  when  the  catastrophic  economic  effects  of  the 
depression  necessitated  a  great  expansion  in  welfare  payments;  and 

(3)  since  the  early  1950's,  when  the  requirements  of  an  expanding  economy, 
together  with  changing  concepts  of  equity,  resulted  in  rapidly  rising  public 
investment  and  transfer  payments. 

Beginning  with  any  year  in  the  early  1950's,  the  net  capital  debt  has  typically 
doubled  within  the  decade.  It  can  be  seen  from  Chart  4:15a  that  by  1966  net 
capital  debt  had  reached  almost  $1.5  billion. 

60.  In  relation  to  provincial  domestic  product,  net  debt  has  varied  rather 
widely  in  the  course  of  the  past  several  decades.  The  resulting  ratio  is  obviously 
affected  from  year  to  year  not  only  by  the  dollar  increase  in  provincial  debt  but 
also  by  the  uneven  growth  in  provincial  product,  a  variable  influenced  by  economic 
conditions  both  inside  and  outside  Ontario  and  indeed  outside  Canada.  As  a  useful 
measure  of  debt  burden,  the  capital  debt/domestic  product  ratio  stood  at  the 
relatively  low  level  of  8  per  cent  during  the  prosperous  years  of  the  late  1920's, 
rose  to  an  all-time  peak  of  almost  30  per  cent  during  the  depths  of  the  depression, 
when  the  value  of  Ontario's  annual  production  fell  by  one-half  within  four  years, 
and  then  declined  continuously  to  its  lowest  level  of  7  per  cent  during  the  peak  of 
the  post-war  boom  in  1956.  A  subsequent  moderate  rise  has  been  in  part  reversed, 
thanks  to  the  province's  recent  very  rapid  economic  growth,  so  that  in  1965  the 
ratio  approximated  8  per  cent.  It  is  worthy  of  note  that  by  historical  standards, 
the  present  burden  of  provincial  debt  is  near  its  lowest  point. 

61.  By  contrast,  the  post-war  trends  of  both  municipal  and  school  board  debt 
in  Ontario  present  some  disturbing  features.  Chart  4:16  reveals  that  municipal 
gross  debt,  after  declining  during  the  expenditure-rationed  years  of  World  War  II, 
resumed  its  upward  trend  shortly  thereafter  and  in  1964  stood  at  between  four 
and  five  times  its  1939  level,  with  accelerated  increases  in  recent  years.  The  Table 
indicates  that  as  a  proportion  of  provincial  domestic  product,  municipal  debt  has 
risen  steeply  from  an  abnormally  low  post-war  level  of  2.9  per  cent  to  approximately 
5.4  per  cent  two  decades  later.  The  latter  ratio  is,  admittedly,  less  than  half  the 
1939  level  of  10.8  per  cent,  a  level  that,  of  course,  was  unacceptably  high  by  any 
standard. 

116 


Chapter  4:  Table  4:1 — Chart  4:15b 


Provin< 
domes 
produ 

billioj 
of  doUi 

1  1   II 

1 

1    1    1    1 

1     1     1     1 

till 

-, 

\ 

_ 

*» 

1 

*. 

1 

— 

\ 

1 

\\ 

- 

H". 

L         1- 

u; 

\               0° 

D  • 

1              UJ 

^ 

Q  : 

\      ° 

9 

o  : 

1 

1^  *. 

El.      . 

\      < 

O 

u     \ 

\      oZ 

tj 

H       *. 
to       • 

\    < 

3 

LU           • 

"9 

s 

\  h- 

— 

a 

o 

l  LLl 

Cu 

o      \ 

\z 

o 

» 

1 

_J          • 

1 

Q> 

< 

1 

B 

o 

1 

o 

z 

1 



a     Ts 

^     ^ 

> 

•                 1 

—     a     . 

o 

Q!! 

c 

1 

H      ■>  f^ 

1 

02       O  '^ 

<     !=:  o 

I     Q.- 

1 

5    "O 

1 

"-^     c 

a 

1 

x> 

4> 

•o 

•             I 

ra 

Oh 

(3 

U 

•        1 

u 

s 

' 

• 

"cS 

'3 

c 

1               — 

i 

'> 

I 

o 

1 

Ul 

1 

PL, 

. 

^f         c  Is 

_ 

let 
pita 
ebt 

llio 
loll; 

1  1 1 1 

1 1  1 1 

i  1 1 1 

TT 


x>     o 


o  \o 


E-s  e 


8 


I  I  I  I 


TTTT 


1± 


I  I  I  I 


—      H 


117 


The  Ontario  Setting 


MILLIONS  OF  DOLLARS 


1         1 

1          1 

1             1       1 

1                            1 

_ 

"^ 

N                      \ 

\\ 

" 

: 

\^         \ 

iiii 

V 
X 

\.\ 

^ 

\ 

•♦.V                      D  C  ° 

V  \ 

***\.             ^ 

\    \ 

— 

\  \ 

'•ijv 

\  \ 

s 

'♦X 

\\ 

— 

o\ 

•> 

•^ 

> 

\  \ 

ft 

— 

o\ 

\ 

i 

^ 

"3 

\        ^  \ 

\    \\ 

— 

-  .i 

\      ^  \ 

\     ^  \ 

— 

S5 

< 

5  1 

\     M" 

T3 

■o 

•V        ^     \ 

- 

^ 

\  ^  \ 

o 

*\  »  V 



M 

^  \   \ 

« 

•N  \ 

"O 

•\  1 

— 

g 

A 

.  V 1 

CS 

•\' 

.s* 

J  I    - 

'5 

1 

'S 

1 

3 

s 

i 

1 

1 

/,M 

- 

;♦' 

;  J/ 

" 

11' 

•I      - 

- 

•w' 

■h 

:U 

•M 

;/  /        - 

— 

•V' 

1 

- 

1           1 

1             1 

1                            1 

III 

\                1 

- 

8 


MILLIONS  OF  DOLLARS 

118 


Chapter  4:  Paragraphs  59-66 

62.  As  we  emphasize  in  later  parts  of  this  Report,  the  financial  flexibility  of 
Ontario  municipalities  is  severely  limited,  both  by  fiscal  and  by  legal  considerations. 
Restricted  by  overwhelming  reliance  upon  the  real  property  tax  as  the  major  com- 
ponent of  their  revenue  system,  and  obliged  by  law  to  balance  current  expenditures 
with  revenues,  many  municipalities  have  been  driven  to  questionable  spending 
decisions.  In  particular,  there  have  been  persistent  pressures  to  restrain  current 
spending  below  what  might  be  established  as  optimum  levels  and,  more  immediately 
relevant  to  the  present  summary,  there  has  been  a  strong  tendency  to  broaden  the 
category  and  increase  the  level  of  capital  expenditures,  outlays  largely  financed 
through  the  incurring  of  debt.  In  short,  the  municipal  revenue  system  has  been 
hard  pressed  in  the  face  of  the  mushrooming  demands  of  the  post-war  years. 

63.  Again  referring  to  Chart  4:16,  the  trend  of  school  board  gross  debt  is  seen 
to  be  even  less  satisfactory.  It  has  increased  more  than  eleven-fold  since  1939, 
although  as  a  percentage  of  provincial  domestic  product  it  has  in  recent  years 
become  stabilized  at  approximately  4  per  cent — significantly  higher  than  the  1939 
level  of  3  per  cent  and  very  much  above  the  (once  again)  abnormal  war-time  low 
point  of  1  per  cent. 

64.  We  have  chosen  to  refer  to  municipal  and  school  board  debt  in  gross 
terms  only  because  of  the  difiiculty  in  distributing  the  accumulated  sinking  fund 
between  the  two  categories.  While  the  burden  of  their  combined  net  debt  is  by 
definition  less  than  that  of  their  combined  gross  debt,  the  differences  are  seen 
from  Chart  4:16  to  be  sUght  in  many  instances  and  the  same  basic  underlying 
trends  are  obtained  regardless  of  which  of  these  measures  is  employed. 

65.  The  measurement  of  the  burden  of  municipal  and  school  board  debt  in 
terms  of  the  relationship  of  debt  to  provincial  domestic  product  is  much  less  satis- 
factory than  is  that  of  provincial  debt,  for  the  obvious  reason  that  provincial 
domestic  product  cannot  possibly  reflect  satisfactorily  the  widely  differing  economic 
circumstances  of  individual  municipalities  and  school  boards.  While  some  such 
procedure  is  essential  if  any  generaUzations  are  to  be  offered  concerning  the  burden 
of  aggregate  debt,  the  problem  can  be  discussed  realistically  only  in  terms  of  the 
burden  of  a  particular  municipality  or  a  particular  school  board. 

CONCLUSION 

66.  This  chapter  will  have  accomplished  its  objective  if  it  has  oriented  the 
reader  with  respect  to  the  remarkable  fiscal  environment  that  we  have  been  called 
upon  to  examine.  We  have  stressed  the  changes  that  have  taken  place  since  the 
turn  of  the  century,  in  no  small  part  because  change  is  indeed  the  keynote  to  what 
has  happened  in  Ontario  since  our  immediate  predecessor,  the  Maclennan  Com- 
mission, took  stock  of  fiscal  affairs.  Needs  have  multiplied  as  income  has  risen, 
sophisticated  forms  of  taxation  have  been  devised  to  meet  burgeoning  expenditures, 
and  debt  has  assumed  a  new  order  of  magnitude.  But  not  all  is  changed,  and  the 
Toronto  Daily  Star  of  September  14,  1900,  constitutes  a  forceful  reminder.  In  the 
realm  of  international  affairs,  a  geographically  remote  conflict  kept  the  appoint- 
ment of  the  Maclennan  Commission  from  the  front  page.  Lord  Roberts,  announc- 
ing the  flight  of  Kruger  from  his  Boers,  was  quoted  as  saying:  "The  British  Empire 

119 


The  Ontario  Setting 

is  determined  to  complete  the  work  which  has  already  cost  so  many  lives,  and 
carry  to  a  conclusion  the  war  declared  against  her  by  the  late  sons  of  Transvaal 
and  the  Orange  Free  State,  a  war  to  which  there  can  be  only  one  ending."  Mean- 
while, on  the  municipal  front,  it  was  reported  that  the  Toronto  Public  Library 
Board  would  discuss  what  action  should  be  taken  as  a  result  of  the  recent  pruning 
of  $2,000  from  their  estimates  by  Board  of  Control.  Apparently  the  Library  Board 
had  earlier  threatened  legal  action  to  compel  payment  of  the  full  amount  of  their 
estimates,  which  were  within  the  statutory  limits.  Last  but  not  least,  in  the  world 
of  sports,  the  Toronto  Argonauts  expected  "plenty  of  first-class  players"  to  turn  out 
for  the  opening  practice.  The  Hamilton  Tigers  were  already  in  training. 


120 


Appendix 


Appendix  to  Chapter  4 

Table  4:1 
PROVINCE  OF  ONTARIO 

GROSS  MONEY  EXPENDITURES  OF  PROVINCIAL  GOVERNMENT, 
MUNICIPALITIES  AND  SCHOOL  BOARDS,  1939-63 


(thousands  of  dollars) 

Indexes  (1939 

=  100) 

(1) 

(2) 

(3) 

(4) 

(5) 

(6) 

(7) 

(8) 

Provincial 

School 

Total  local 

Provincial 

School 

Total  local 

Year 

government 

Municipalities 

boards 

expenditure 

government 

Municipalities 

boards 

expenditure 

* 

** 

** 

(2  +3) 
171,361 

1939.,.. 

144,776 

119,622 

51,739 

100.00 

100.00 

100.00 

100.00 

1940 

135,937 

105,078 

50,114 

155,192 

93.89 

87.84 

96.86 

90.56 

1941 

118,096 

97,955 

50,556 

148,511 

81.57 

81.89 

97.71 

86.67 

1942 

128,911 

92,296 

51,545 

143,841 

89.04 

77.16 

99.63 

83.94 

1943 

113,221 

93,715 

53,711 

147,426 

78.20 

78.34 

103.81 

86.03 

1944 

122,772 

86,398 

57,313 

143,711 

84.80 

72.23 

110.77 

83.86 

1945 

134,973 

103,280 

65,263 

168,543 

93.23 

86.34 

126.14 

98.36 

1946 

148.531 

120,656 

71,060 

191,716 

102.59 

100.86 

137.34 

111.88 

1947 

183,462 

145,273 

85,508 

230,781 

126.72 

121.44 

165.27 

134.68 

1948 

222,749 

179,417 

106,299 

285,716 

153.86 

149.99 

205.45 

166.73 

1949 

276,307 

186,129 

125,192 

311,321 

190.85 

155.60 

241.97 

181.68 

1950 

317,346 

206,425 

142,121 

348,546 

219.20 

172.56 

274.69 

203.40 

1951 

344,873 

227,963 

172,910 

400,873 

238.21 

190.57 

334.20 

233.93 

1952. . .. 

410,828 

253,793 

206,411 

460,204 

283.76 

212.16 

398.95 

268.56 

1953 

425,404 

279,779 

219,225 

499,004 

293.83 

233.89 

423.71 

291.20 

1954 

437,446 

388,930 

248,138 

637,068 

302.15 

325.13 

479.60 

371.77 

1955 

464,415 

419,500 

277,590 

697,090 

320.78 

350.69 

536.52 

406.80 

1956 

543,628 

459,349 

310,800 

770,149 

375.49 

384.00 

600.71 

449.43 

1957. ... 

617,736 

524,694 

358,063 

882,757 

426.68 

438.63 

692.06 

515.14 

19.'58.  .  .. 

707,893 

574,165 

391,484 

965,649 

488.95 

479.98 

756.65 

563.52 

1959 

818,981 

641,172 

458,323 

1,099,495 

565.69 

536.00 

885.84 

641.62 

1960. .  .. 

982,759 

711,349 

527,853 

1,239.202 

678.81 

594.66 

1,020.22 

723.15 

1961 

.  .  .  1,026,211 

755,514 

548,255 

1,303,769 

708.83 

631.58 

1,059.66 

760.83 

1962 

.  .  .   1,164,509 

845,050 

672,221 

1,517,271 

804.35 

706.43 

1,299.25 

885.42 

1963 

. .  .  1,425,102 

919,330 

737,281 

1,656,611 

984.35 

768.53 

1.425.00 

966.74 

1964 

...  1,462,986 

1,010.52 

Source:  Ontario.  Department  of  Municipal  Affairs,  Annual  Report  of  Municipal  Statistics,  1939-1963.  Canada' 
Dominion  Bureau  of  Statistics,  Financial  Statistics  of  Municipal  Governments,  1944-1962.  Ontario,  Department  of 
Education,  Report  of  the  Minister  1939-1964.  Canada,  Department  of  Finance,  Federal-Provincial  Conditional 
Grant  and  Shared-Cost  Programs,  1962.    Ontario,  Public  Accounts,  1939-1964. 

♦Fiscal  years  ending  March  31. 

♦♦Municipal  and  school  board  data  include  a  small  degree  of  double  counting. 


121 


The  Ontario  Setting 


Table  4:2 

PROVINCE  OF  ONTARIO 

NET  MONEY  EXPENDITURES  OF  PROVINCIAL  GOVERNMENT, 
MUNICIPALITIES  AND  SCHOOL  BOARDS,  1939-63 


(thousands  of  dollars) 

Indexes  (1939 

=  100) 

(1) 

(2) 

(3) 

(4) 

(5) 

(6) 

(7) 

(8) 

Provincial 

School 

Total  local 

Provincial 

School 

Total  local 

Year 

government 

Municipalities 

boards 

expenditure 
(2  +3) 

149,839 

government 

Municipalities 

boards 

ex5>enditure 

1939 

127,762 

105,116 

44,723 

100.00 

100.00 

100.00 

100.00 

1940 

118,447 

93,273 

43,140 

136,413 

92.70 

88.73 

96.46 

91.04 

1941 

104,575 

88.711 

42,902 

131,613 

81.85 

84.39 

95.93 

87.84 

1942 

115,930 

83,522 

43,715 

127,237 

90.73 

79.46 

97.75 

84.92 

1943 

100,202 

85,914 

45,434 

131,348 

78.42 

81.73 

101.59 

87.66 

1944 

109,717 

77,353 

48,328 

125,681 

85.87 

73.59 

108.06 

83.88 

1945 

120,712 

97,290 

38,656 

135,946 

94.48 

92.55 

86.43 

90.73 

1946 

132,301 

112,439 

41,770 

154,209 

103.55 

106.97 

93.40 

102.92 

1947 

163,891 

129,147 

55,304 

184,451 

128.27 

122.86 

123.66 

123.10 

1948 

201,134 

155,368 

73,721 

229,089 

157.42 

147.81 

164.84 

152.89 

1949 

253,131 

157,520 

87,599 

245,119 

198.12 

149.85 

195.87 

163.59 

1950 

282,801 

174,977 

99,460 

274,437 

221.34 

166.46 

222.39 

183.15 

1951 

305,384 

191,828 

125,555 

317,383 

239.02 

182.49 

280.74 

211.82 

1952 

372,315 

212,294 

152,442 

364,736 

291.41 

201.96 

340.86 

243.42 

1953 

404,593 

236,184 

161,344 

397,528 

316.67 

224.69 

360.76 

265.30 

1954 

419,713 

332,567 

180,182 

512,749 

328.51 

316.38 

402.89 

342.20 

1955 

441,268 

352,367 

203,940 

556,307 

345.38 

335.22 

456.01 

371.27 

1956 

522,300 

386,306 

230,511 

616,817 

408.80 

367.50 

515.42 

411.65 

1957 

592,290 

433.650 

259,880 

693,530 

463.58 

412.54 

581.09 

462.85 

1958 

671,329 

467,721 

261,932 

729,653 

525.45 

444.96 

585.68 

486.96 

1959 

750,138 

518,697 

308,167 

826,864 

587.13 

493.45 

689.06 

551.83 

1960 

842,341 

575,860 

367,063 

942,923 

659.30 

547.83 

820.75 

629.29 

1961 

871,578 

611,458 

363,130 

974,588 

682.18 

581.70 

811.96 

650.42 

1962 

977.479 

689,494 

405,026 

1,094,520 

765.08 

655.94 

905.63 

730.46 

1963 

1,106,542 

753,793 

432,696 

1,186,489 

866.10 

717.11 

967.50 

791.84 

1964 

1,180,745 

924.18 

Source:  Canada,  Dominion  Bureau  of  Statistics,  Financial  Statistics  of  Municipal  Governments,  1944-1962.  Ontario, 
Department  of  Municipal  Affairs,  Annua!  Reports  of  Municipal  Statistics,  1939-1963  Ontario,  Department  of 
Education,  Report  of  the  Minister,  1939-1964.     Ontario,  Public  Accounts,  1939-1964. 

♦Fiscal  years  ending  March  31. 

♦♦Municipal  and  school  board  data  include  a  small  degree  of  double  counting. 


122 


Chapter  4:  Appendix 

Table  4:3 
PROVINCE  OF  ONTARIO 

NET  MONEY  EXPENDITURES  AS  A  PERCENTAGE  OF  GROSS  MONEY  EXPENDITURES, 
PROVINCIAL  GOVERNMENT,  MUNICIPALITIES  AND  SCHOOL  BOARDS.  1939-63 


Year 

(1) 
Provincial 
government* 

(2) 

Municipalities 

87.87% 

(3) 
School  boards 

1939 

88.25% 

86.44% 

1940 

87.13 

88.77 

86.08 

1941 

88.55 

90.56 

84.86 

1942 

89.93 

90.49 

84.81 

1943 

88.50 

91.68 

84.59 

1944 

89.37 

89.53 

84.32 

1945..- 

89.43 

94.20 

59.23 

1946 

89.07 

93.19 

58.78 

1947 

89.33 

88.90 

64.68 

1948 

90.30 

86.60 

69.35 

1949 

91.61 

84.63 

69.97 

1950 

89.11 

84.77 

69.98 

1951 

88.55 

84.15 

72.61 

1952 

90.63 

83.65 

73.85 

1963 

95.11 

84.42 

73.60 

1964 

95.95 

85.51 

72.61 

1955 

95.02 

84.00 

73.47 

1956 

96.08 

84.10 

74.17 

1957 

95.88 

82.65 

72.58 

1958 

94.83 

81.46 

66.91 

1959 

91.59 

80.90 

67.24 

1960 

85.71 

80.95 

69.54 

1961 

84.93 

80.93 

66.23 

1962 

83.94 

81.59 

60.25 

1963 

77.65 

81.99 

58.69 

1964 

80.71 

Source :  Tables  4 : 1  and  4 : 2 
♦Fiscal  years  ending  March  31. 


123 


The  Ontario  Setting 


Table  4:4 

PROVINCE  OF  ONTARIO 

NET  REAL  EXPENDITURES  OF  PROVINCIAL  GOVERNMENT, 
MUNICIPALITIES  AND  SCHOOL  BOARDS,  1939-63* 


(thousands  of  1949  dollars) 

Indexes  (1939 

=  100) 

Year 

(1) 
Provincial 
government 

♦* 

(2) 
Municipalities 

(3) 
School 
boards 

(4) 
Total  local 
expenditure 

(2+3) 

251,867 

(5) 
Provincial 
government 

(6) 
Municipalities 

(7) 
School 
boards 

(8) 
Total  local 
expenditure 

1939 

213,737 

176,634 

75,233 

100.00 

100.00 

100.00 

100.00 

1940 

195,735 

148,710 

69,042 

217,752 

91.58 

84.19 

91.77 

86.46 

1941 

164,688 

135,299 

65,776 

201,075 

77.05 

76.60 

87.43 

79.83 

1942 

173,070 

118,087 

61,646 

179,733 

80.97 

66.85 

81.94 

71.36 

1943 

139.999 

117,372 

62,101 

179,473 

65.50 

66.45 

82.54 

71.26 

1944 

148,920 

101,742 

63,350 

165,092 

69.67 

57.60 

84.21 

65.55 

1945 

157,570 

124,303 

49,078 

173,381 

73.72 

70.37 

65.23 

68.84 

1946 

167,964 

144,385 

53,505 

197,890 

78.58 

81.74 

71.12 

78.57 

1947 

205,953 

154,039 

65,966 

220,005 

96.36 

87.21 

87.68 

87.35 

1948 

232,637 

160,355 

77,593 

237,948 

108.84 

90.78 

103.14 

94.47 

1949 

263,222 

1.57,520 

87,599 

245,119 

123.15 

89.18 

116.44 

97.32 

1950 

275,487 

167,673 

95,068 

262,741 

128.89 

94.93 

126.36 

104.32 

1951 

285,298 

165,123 

107,911 

273,034 

133.48 

93.48 

143.44 

108.40 

1952 

313,609 

175,543 

125,599 

301,142 

146.73 

99.38 

166.95 

119.56 

1953 

330,740 

189,305 

128,943 

318,248 

154.74 

107.17 

171.39 

126.36 

1954 

332,903 

258,815 

140,110 

398,925 

155.75 

146.53 

186.23 

158.39 

1956 

341,089 

268,026 

154.220 

422,246 

159.58 

151.74 

204.99 

167.65 

1956 

395,357 

279,735 

165,897 

445,632 

184.97 

158.37 

220.51 

176.93 

1957 

425,786 

299,876 

178,477 

478,353 

199.21 

169.77 

237.23 

189.92 

1958 

458,936 

325,928 

179,271 

505,199 

214.72 

184.52 

238.29 

200.58 

1959 

504,174 

350,849 

204,219 

555,068 

235.88 

198.63 

271.45 

220.38 

1960 

547,645 

384,112 

238,198 

622,310 

256.22 

217.46 

316.61 

247.08 

1961 

547,074 

410,623 

230,596 

641,219 

255.95 

232.47 

306.51 

254.59 

1962 

615,904 

442,977 

246,498 

689,475 

288.16 

250.79 

327.65 

273.75 

1963 

665,700 

462,421 

253,250 

715,671 

306.78 

261.80 

336.62 

284.15 

1964 

684,250 

320.13 

Source:  Canada,  Dominion  Bureau  of  Statistics,  National  Accounts,  1938-1964,  and  Table  4:2. 

*The  index  used  in  this  table  and  in  subsequent  tables  for  deflation  is  a  composite  index  based  on  an  estimated  dis- 
tribution between  expenditure  on  current  goods  and  services  (index  of  current  government  expenditure),  gross 
fixed  capital  formation  (with  its  own  price  index  in  the  National  Accounts);  and  transfer  payments  to  individuals 
(index  for  personal  spending  on  consumer  goods  and  services) . 

**Fi8cal  years  ending  March  31. 


124 


Chapter  4:  Appendix 


Table  4:5 
PROVINCE  OF  ONTARIO 

NET  REAL  PER-CAPITA  EXPENDITURES  OF  PROVINCIAL  GOVERNMENT, 
MUNICIPALITIES  AND  SCHOOL  BOARDS,  1939-63 


Year  Provincial  government* 

1949 

dollars  Index** 

1939 S  58.21  100.00 

1940 52.79  90.69 

1941 43.95  75.50 

1942 45.69  78.49 

1943 36.05  61.93 

1944 38.04  65.35 

1945 39.76  68.30 

1946 41.99  72.14 

1947 50.32  86.45 

1948 55.71  95.71 

1949 61.57  105.77 

1950 62.93  108.11 

1951 63.81  109.62 

1952 68.21  117.18 

1953 69.08  118.67 

1954 67.38  115.75 

1955 66.68  114.55 

1956 75.08  128.98 

1957 78.78  135.34 

1958 81.43  139.89 

1959 86.61  148.79 

1960 91.75  157.62 

1961 89.52  153.79 

1962 98.77  169.68 

1963 104.97  180.33 

1964 106.12  182.31 


Munic 

ipalities 
Index*** 

School  boards 

1949 
dollars 

1949 
dollars 

Index*** 

$47.63 

100.00 

$20.29 

100.00 

39.69 

83.33 

18.43 

90.83 

35.72 

74.99 

17.36 

85.56 

30.40 

63.83 

15.87 

78,22 

29.98 

62.94 

15.86 

78.17 

25.67 

53.89 

15.99 

78.81 

31.08 

65.25 

12.27 

60.47 

35.28 

74.07 

13.07 

64.42 

36.89 

77.45 

15.80 

77.87 

38.21 

80.22 

18.15 

89.45 

35.98 

75.54 

20.01 

98.62 

37.50 

78.73 

21.26 

104.78 

35.91 

75.39 

23.47 

115.67 

36.66 

76.97 

26.23 

129.28 

38.31 

80.43 

26.10 

128.63 

50.60 

106.24 

27.39 

134.99 

50.90 

106.87 

29.29 

144.36 

51.75 

108.65 

30.69 

151.26 

53.20 

111.69 

31.67 

156.09 

55.99 

117.55 

30.80 

151.80 

58.78 

123.41 

34.21 

168.61 

62.56 

131.35 

38.98 

192.11 

65.44 

137.39 

36.98 

18226 

69.54 

146.00 

38.87 

191.57 

71.53 

150.18 

39.28 

193.59 

Source:        Canada,  Dominion  Bureau  of  Statistics,  National  Accounts,  1938-1964,  and  Table  4:4. 

♦Fiscal  years  ending  March  31. 

**1938-39  =  100.     ***  1939  =  100. 

Provincial  figures  based  on  population  at  June  1  of  years  preceding  indicated  years. 


125 


The  Ontario  Setting 

Table  4:6a 
PROVINCE  OF  ONTARIO 

GOVERNMENT  EXPENDITURE  BY  LEVEL  OF  ULTIMATE  SPENDING  RESPONSIBILITY,  1939-63 

MONEY  EXPENDITURES 


(thousands  of  dollars) 

Indexes  (1939= 

=  100) 

Year 

Provincial 
government* 

Municipalities 
119,622 

School  boards 

Provincial 
government 

100.00 

Municipalities 
100.00 

School  boards 

1939 

119,958 

51,739 

100.00 

1940 
1941 
1942 
1943 
1944 

114,425 
99,317 

112,019 
96,917 

106.694 

105,078 
97,955 
92.296 
93,715 
86,398 

50,114 
50,556 
51.545 
53.711 
57,313 

95.39 
82.79 
93.38 
80.79 
88.94 

87.84 
81.89 
77.16 
78.34 
72.23 

96.86 

97.71 

99.63 

103.81 

110.77 

1945 
1946 
1947 
1948 
1949 

116,943 
115.934 
144,912 
170,574 
216.355 

103,280 
120,656 
145,273 
179,417 
186,129 

65,263 
71,060 
85,508 
106,299 
125,192 

97.49 
96.65 
120.80 
142.19 
180.36 

86.34 
100.86 
121.44 
149.99 
155.60 

126.14 
137.34 
165.27 
205.45 
241.97 

1950 
1951 
1952 
1953 
1954 

246.199 
266,503 
324,180 
328,115 
335,427 

206,425 
227,963 
253,793 
279,779 
388,930 

142,121 
172,910 
206,411 
219,225 
248,138 

205.24 
222.16 
270.24 
273.52 
279.62 

172.56 
190.57 
212.16 
233.89 
325.13 

274.69 
334.20 
398.95 
423.71 
479.60 

1955 
1956 
1957 
1958 
1959 

337.078 
408,477 
462,297 
513,916 
584,340 

419,500 
459,349 
524.694 
574,165 
641,172 

277,590 
310,800 
358,063 
391,484 
458,323 

281.00 
340.52 
385.38 
428.41 
487.12 

350.69 
384.00 
438.63 
479.98 
536.00 

536.52 
600.71 
692.06 
756.65 
885.84 

1960 
1961 
1962 
1963 

709,813 
722,731 
819,702 
889,766 

711,349 
755,514 
845,050 
919,330 

527,853 
548,255 
672,221 
737,281 

591.72 
602.49 
683.32 
741.73 

594.66 
631.58 
706.43 
768.53 

1,020  22 
1,059.66 
1,299.25 
1,425.00 

Source:  Table  4:1;     Canada,  Dominion  Bureau  of  Statistics,  Historical  Review,  Financial  Statistics  of  Governments  in 
Canada,  1962-62,  and  data  supplied  by  the  Ontario  Department  of  Economics  and  Development. 
♦Fiscal  years  ending  March  31. 

Table  4:6b 
PROVINCE  OF  ONTARIO 

GOVERNMENT  EXPENDITURE  BY  LEVEL  OF  ULTIMATE  SPENDING  RESPONSIBILITY.  1939-63 

REAL  EXPENDITURES 


(thousands  of  1949  dollars) 

Indexes  (1939  = 

=  100) 

Year 

Provincial 
government* 

Municipalities 
201,012 

School  boards 

Provincial 
government 

Municipalities 
100.00 

School  boards 

1939 

200,666 

87,029 

100.00 

100.00 

1940 
1941 
1942 
1943 
1944 

189,038 
156,405 
167,242 
135,416 
144,807 

167,535 
149,390 
130,491 
128.026 
113,637 

80,208 
77,516 
72,691 
73.416 
75,125 

94.21 
77.94 
83.34 
67.48 
72.16 

83.35 
74.32 
64.92 
63.69 
56.53 

92.16 
89.07 
83.53 
84.36 
86.32 

1945 
1946 
1947 
1948 
1949 

152,647 
147,180 
182.096 
197,287 
224,971 

131,953 
154,945 
173,274 
185,176 
186,129 

82,863 
91.021 
101,990 
111,882 
125,192 

76.07 
73.35 
90.75 
98.32 
112.11 

65.64 
77.08 
86.20 
92.12 
92.60 

95.21 
104.59 
117.19 
128.56 
143.85 

1960 
1951 
1952 
1953 
1954 

239,843 
248,975 
273,063 
268,227 
266,043 

197,801 
196,232 
209,850 
224,254 
302,669 

135,832 
148,612 
170,068 
175,198 
192,953 

119.52 
124.07 
136.08 
133.67 
132.58 

98.40 

97.62 

104.40 

111.56 

150.57 

156.08 
170.76 
195.42 
201.31 
221.71 

1955 
1966 
1957 
1958 
1969 

260,553 
309,195 
332,325 
351,323 
392,728 

319,084 
332,621 
362,834 
400,115 
433,693 

209,914 
223,678 
245,906 
267,938 
303,726 

129.84 
154.08 
165.61 
175.08 
195.71 

158.74 
165.47 
180,50 
199.05 
215.75 

241.20 
257.02 
282.56 
307.87 
348.99 

1960 
1961 
1962 
1963 

461,487 
453,635 
516,478 
527,237 

474,486 
507,363 
542,917 
563,972 

342,539 
348,164 
409,118 
431,512 

229.98 
226.06 
257.38 
262.74 

236.05 
252.40 
270.09 
280.57 

393.59 
400.06 
470.09 
495.83 

Source:  Table  4:6a. 

♦Fiscal  years  ending  March  31. 


126 


Chapter  4:  Appendix 

Table  4:6c 
PROVINCE  OF  ONTARIO 

GOVERNMENT  EXPENDITURE  BY  LEVEL  OF  ULTIMATE  SPENDING  RESPONSIBILITY,  1939-63 
REAL  PER-CAPITA  EXPENDITURES 


(1949  dollars) 

Indexes  (1939= 

=  100) 

Provincial 

Provincial 

Year 

government* 

Municipalities 
54.21 

School  boards 

government 
100.00 

Municipalities 
100.00 

School  boards 

1939 

54.65 

23.47 

100.00 

1940 

50.98 

44.71 

21.41 

93.28 

82.48 

91.22 

1941 

41.74 

39.44 

20.46 

76.38 

72.75 

87.18 

1942 

44.15 

33.60 

18.72 

80.79 

61.98 

79.76 

1943 

34.87 

32.70 

18.75 

63.81 

60.32 

79.89 

1944 

36.99 

28.67 

18.96 

67.69 

52.89 

80.78 

1945 

38.52 

32.99 

20.72 

70.48 

60.86 

88.28 

1946 

36.80 

37.86 

22.24 

67.34 

69.84 

94.76 

1947 

44.49 

41.49 

24.42 

81.41 

76.54 

104.05 

1948  . 

47.24 

43.32 

26.17 

86.44 

79.91 

111.50 

1949 

52.62 

42.51 

28.60 

96.29 

78.42 

121.86 

1950 

54.78 

44.24 

30.38 

100.24 

81.61 

129.44 

1951 

55.69 

42.68 

32.32 

101.90 

78.73 

137.71 

1952 

59.39 

43.83 

35.52 

108.67 

80.85 

151.34 

1953 

66.02 

45.39 

35.46 

102.51 

83.73 

151.09 

1954 

53.84 

59.17 

37.72 

98.52 

109.15 

160.72 

1955 

50.94 

60.59 

39.86 

93.21 

111.77 

169.83 

1956 

58.72 

61.54 

41.38 

107.45 

113.52 

176.31 

1957 

61.48 

64.38 

43.63 

112.50 

118.76 

185.90 

1958 

62.34 

68.74 

46.03 

114.07 

126.80 

196.12 

1959 

67.47 

72.66 

50.88 

123.46 

134.03 

216.79 

1960 

77.31 

77.64 

56.05 

141.46 

143.22 

238.82 

1961 

74.23 

81.36 

55.83 

135.83 

150.08 

237.88 

1962 

82.82 

85.61 

64.51 

151.55 

157.92 

274.86 

1963 

83.13 

87.46 

66.92 

152.11 

161.34 

285.13 

Source:  Tables  4:6a  and  4:6b. 
♦Fiscal  years  ending  March  31. 


Table  4:7 
PROVINCE  OF  ONTARIO 

PROVINCIAL  AND  LOCAL  NET  REAL  EXPENDITURE 
ON  GOODS  AND  SERVICES;  NATIONAL  ACCOUNTS  BASIS,  1939-63 


(1) 


(2) 


(thousands  of  1949  dollars) 

(3)  (4) 


(5) 


(6) 


Year 
1939. 

1940. 
1941. 
1942. 
1943. 
1944. 

1945. 
1946. 
1947. 
1948. 
1949. 

1950. 
1951. 
1952. 
1953. 
1954. 

1955. 
1956. 
1957. 
1958. 
1959. 

1960. 
1961. 
1962. 
1963. 


Provincial 
expenditure* 

Local 
expenditure 

Estimated 

real  provincial 

domestic  product 

(1)  as  a 

percentage 

of  (3) 

(2)  as  a 

percentage 

of  (3) 

(l)-h(2)asa 

percentage 

of  (3) 

142,874 

180,242 

3,538,000 

4.04 

5.09 

9.13 

119,383 
125,885 
104,418 
100,624 
108,678 

165,221 
164,851 
149,995 
153,023 
143,802 

4,076,000 
4,745,000 
5,377,000 
5.712,000 
5,750,000 

2.93 
2.65 
1.94 
1.76 
1.89 

4.05 
3.47 
2.79 
2.68 
2.50 

6.98 
6.12 
4.73 
4.44 
4.39 

118,319 
155,269 
190,972 
209,740 
225,149 

128,948 
143,692 
177,095 
198,979 
213,567 

5,691,000 
5,341,000 
5,388,000 
5,473,000 
5,776,000 

2.08 
2.91 
3.54 
3.83 
3.90 

2.27 
2.69 
3.29 
3.64 
3.70 

4.35 
5.60 
6.83 
7.47 
760 

234,836 
249,008 
273,275 
280,018 
289,971 

229,390 
238,008 
262,363 
274,602 
347,396 

6,283,000 
6,454,000 
6,912,000 
7,258,000 
7,240,000 

3.74 
3.86 
3.95 
3.86 
4.01 

3.65 
3.69 
3.80 
3.78 
4.80 

7.39 
7.55 
7.75 
7.64 
8.80 

327,320 
356,231 
397,515 
453,663 
483,831 

365,143 
380,120 
405,218 
413,666 
446,922 

7,915,000 
8,376,000 
8,757,000 
8,845,000 
9,147,000 

4.14 
4.25 
4.54 
5.13 
5.29 

4.61 
4.54 
4.63 
4.68 
4.89 

8.75 
8.79 
9.17 
9.81 
10.18 

483,456 
522,544 
561.118 
579,980 

459,076 
510,058 
540,123 
549,739 

9,256,000 

9,507,000 

9,905,000 

10,390,000 

5.22 
5.50 
5.66 
5.58 

4.96 
5.37 
5.45 
5.29 

10.18 
10.86 
11.11 
10.87 

Source:  Canada,  Dominion  Bureau  of  Statistics,   National  Accounts.   1926-1956,   Table   49;    1955-1964,   Table  49. 
Canada,  Dominion  Bureau  of  Statistics,  unpublished  tables  provided  to  The  Ontario  Committee  on  Taxation. 
♦Fiscal  years  ending  March  31. 


127 


The  Ontario  Setting 


Table  4:8 
PROVINCE  OF  ONTARIO 

FUNCTIONAL  CLASSIFICATION  OF  NET  EXPENDITURES 
OF  PROVINCIAL  GOVERNMENT,  1945-64* 


(thousands  of  dollars) 

enforce- 

Fiscal 
year 

Educa- 
tion 

Health 

Welfare 

12.826 
12,908 
13,490 
13,700 
17,718 

Highways 

18,290 
22,619 
45,378 
62,026 
67,790 

Natural 
resources 

9.706 
10.427 
12,371 
13,702 
17,373 

ment 

and 

reform 

Munici- 
pal 
affairs 

Public 
debt 

Public 
works 

Power 
bonus 

Miscel- 
laneous 

1945. 
1946. 
1947. 
1948. 
1949. 

25.748 
32,258 
34,134 
41,431 
49,418 

11.632 
12,631 
15,551 
20.119 
28.650 

4,538 
6,177 
6,200 
8,217 
11,311 

6,417 
3,361 
3,453 
3.695 
3.952 

26,109 
25.447 
24.812 
22,872 
34,422 

1,219 
1,390 
2,554 
5,431 
7,703 

1,310 
1,680 
1,660 
4,565 
8,028 

2,917 
3,403 
4,288 
5,376 
6,766 

1950. 
1951. 
1952. 
1953. 
1954. 

53,935 
60,894 
71,014 
79,676 
86,094 

32,265 
33.768 
44,509 
50,530 
52,245 

21,650 
23.938 
24.637 
21,909 
23.700 

72,042 

82.280 

102,180 

120,213 

113,967 

20,748 
18.343 
19.215 
20.634 
19,902 

11,204 
12.315 
17.040 
16.084 
17,320 

4.009 
4,480 
5.214 
7.622 
9.353 

38,975 
41,457 
54,726 
52.903 
52.456 

8,914 
11,753 
12,152 
12,693 
22,211 

10,622 
7,297 

10,224 
8,826 
9,412 

8.437 

8,859 

11.404 

13.503 

13.053 

1955. 
1956. 
1957. 
1958. 
1959. 

96,209 
105,038 
112.891 
147,933 
183,661 

57,019 
59,193 
62.303 
65.965 
77,323 

26.054 
27,000 
29.303 
36.143 
41,920 

110,169 
156,353 
197,915 
214.197 
229,459 

19,025 
24.765 
24.002 
27.822 
29,719 

19,031 
21.976 
22.412 
27,019 
30,113 

18,333 
15.869 
16,875 
25,788 
28,079 

47,014 
58.094 
67.005 
46,959 
50.285 

26,652 
30,366 
35,485 
50,368 
49,505 

7,297 
7,976 
6,144 
7,359 
1,454 

14.465 
15.670 
17.955 
21,776 
28,620 

1960. 
1961. 
1962. 
1963. 
1964. 

211.908 
235,069 
270,623 
357,695 
391,038 

84,060 
88.960 
130,316 
144.303 
122.026 

44.624 
51,019 
54,447 
56,676 
60,690 

250,930 
239,641 
245.000 
252,143 
281.382 

33.888 
33.356 
37,178 
38,213 
42.048 

34,562 
33,854 
36.603 
39,623 

47,878 

32,414 
36,856 
39,530 
41,771 
44,955 

68,210 
78,233 
86.116 
96.407 
102,239 

49,813 
42.019 
39.621 
37,381 
40,651 

1,324 
511 
544 
922 
824 

30,608 
32,060 
37,501 
41,408 
47.014 

Source:  Ontario,  Public  Accounts,  1945-1964. 
♦Net  ordinary  and  net  capital  expenditures. 


Table  4:9 

PROVINCE  OF  ONTARIO 

PERCENTAGE  DISTRIBUTION  OF  FUNCTIONAL  CLASSIFICATION  OF  NET  EXPENDITURES 
OF  PROVINCIAL  GOVERNMENT,  1945-64* 


(percentages) 

Law 

enforce- 

ment 

Munici- 

Fiscal 

Educa- 

High- 

Natural 

and 

pal 

Public 

Public 

Power 

Miscel- 

year 

tion 

Health 

Welfare 

ways 

resources 

reform 

affairs 

debt 

works 

bonus 

laneous 

1945 

21.33 

9.63 

10.63 

15.15 

8.04 

3.76 

5.32 

21.63 

1.01 

1.08 

2.42 

1946.... 

24.38 

9.55 

9.76 

17.10 

7.88 

4.67 

2.54 

19.23 

1.05 

1.27 

2.57 

1947.... 

20.83 

9.49 

8.23 

27.69 

7.55 

3.78 

2.11 

15.14 

1.56 

1.01 

2.61 

1948. . . . 

20.60 

10.00 

6.81 

30.84 

6.81 

4.09 

1.84 

11.37 

2.70 

2.27 

2.67 

1949.... 

.       19.52 

11.32 

7.00 

26.78 

6.86 

4.47 

1.56 

13.60 

3.04 

3.18 

2.67 

1950.... 

19.07 

11.41 

7.66 

25.47 

7.34 

3.96 

1.42 

13.78 

3.15 

3.76 

2.98 

1951.... 

19.94 

11.06 

7.84 

26.94 

6.00 

4.03 

1.47 

13.58 

3.85 

2.39 

2.90 

1952.... 

19.07 

11.96 

6.62 

27.44 

5.16 

4.58 

1.40 

14.70 

3.26 

2.75 

3.06 

1953. . . . 

.       19.69 

12.49 

5.42 

29.71 

5.09 

3.98 

1.88 

13.08 

3.14 

2.18 

3.34 

1954.... 

20.51 

12.45 

5.65 

27.15 

4.74 

4.13 

2.23 

12.50 

5.29 

2.24 

3.11 

1955... 

21.80 

12.92 

5.91 

24.97 

4.31 

4.31 

4.16 

10.65 

6.04 

1.65 

3.28 

1956.... 

20.11 

11.33 

5.17 

29.94 

4.74 

4.21 

3.04 

11.12 

5.81 

1.53 

3.00 

1957.... 

19.06 

10.52 

4.95 

3342 

4.05 

3.78 

2.85 

11.31 

5.99 

1.04 

3.03 

1958. . . . 

.      22.04 

9.83 

5.38 

31.91 

4.15 

4.02 

3.84 

6.99 

7.50 

1.10 

3.24 

1959.... 

24.48 

1031 

5.59 

30.59 

3.96 

4.02 

3.74 

6.70 

6.60 

0.19 

3.82 

1960. . . . 

25.16 

9.98 

5.30 

29.79 

4.02 

4.10 

3.85 

8.10 

5.91 

0.16 

3.63 

1961.... 

.       26.97 

10.21 

5.85 

27.50 

3.83 

3.88 

4.23 

8.98 

4.82 

0.06 

3.67 

1962.... 

.       27.69 

1333 

5.57 

25.07 

3.80 

3.74 

4.04 

8.81 

4.05 

0.06 

3.84 

1963.... 

.      32  33 

13.04 

5.12 

22.79 

3.45 

3.58 

3.78 

8.71 

3.>38 

0.08 

3.74 

1964..  .. 

33.12 

10.34 

5.14 

23.83 

3.56 

4.05 

3.81 

8.66 

3.44 

0.07 

3.98 

Source:  Table  4:8. 

*Net  ordinary  and  net  capital  expenditures. 


128 


Chapter  4:  Appendix 


Table  4:10 
PROVINCE  OF  ONTARIO 

FUNCTIONAL  CLASSIFICATION  OF  NET 
GENERAL  EXPENDITURES  OF  LOCAL  GOVERNMENTS,  1951-63 


(thousands  of  dollars) 


Protection 
Sanitation  to 

Highways        and  persons      General 

Educa-         and  waste  and         govern- 

Year  tion  roads        removal     property       ment 


Social 
Health      welfare 


1945..      34,517         20,189 
1946-1950  not  available 


Debt 


Deficits 
of 
municipal 
enter-      Miscel- 
prises      laneous      Total 


8,010         18,293       14,438       11,005         5,283         5,965 


804 


7,187       125,691 


1951. . 

111,443 

36,184 

21,716 

47,304 

17,883 

13,917 

12,275 

9,977 

821 

22,185 

293,705 

1952.  . 

136,353 

43,786 

21,877 

43,180 

22,948 

18,548 

13,486 

12,422 

1,558 

25,041 

339,199 

1953.. 

144,261 

50,713 

32,107 

46,358 

26,838 

19,936 

14,348 

15,754 

1,677 

27,076 

379,068 

1954.. 

160,999 

71,031 

92,046 

56,528 

31,293 

25,917 

17,262 

20,443 

1,756 

27,720 

504,995 

1955.. 

174,362 

104,156 

57,315 

70,684 

39,050 

22,429 

18,848 

22,172 

1,819 

29,610 

540,445 

1956.. 

198,699 

100,190 

73,356 

72,190 

46,239 

27,080 

20,367 

26,791 

4,205 

32,552 

601,669 

1957. . 

229,190 

152,635 

64,040 

77,510 

46,068 

30,049 

18,960 

36,307 

2,112 

41,903 

698,774 

1958.. 

225,630 

158,959 

68,851 

85,678 

50,772 

27,679 

21,715 

38,651 

2,562 

46,766 

727,263 

1959.. 

263,830 

180,558 

77,192 

95,430 

54,560 

24,989 

22,101 

45,759 

3,011 

52,756 

820.186 

I960.. 

306,307 

188,433 

84,993 

102,289 

60,199 

31,209 

25,363 

56,557 

10,953 

63,282 

929,585 

1961.. 

318,378 

167.861 

109,413 

113,457 

58,066 

29,693 

24,406 

65,479 

10,888 

58,239 

955,880 

1962. . 

330,527 

204,499 

101,742 

122,211 

65,094 

38,369 

24,944 

70,889 

12,158 

72,264 

1,042,697 

1963. . 

360,659 

209,143 

111,152 

127,364 

77,646 

22,100 

25,008 

79,146 

15,134 

75,426 

1,102,778 

Source:  Federal-Provincial  Conference  1955,  Comparative  Statistics  of  Public  Finance,  Vol.  I.  Canada,  Dominion  Bureau 
of  Statistics,  Historical  Review,  Financial  Statistics  of  Governments  in  Canada,  1952-6Z;  Municipal  Government  Finance, 
1963. 


Table  4:11 
PROVINCE  OF  ONTARIO 

PERCENTAGE  DISTRIBUTION  OF  FUNCTIONAL  CLASSIFICATION 
OF  NET  GENERAL  EXPENDITURES  OF  LOCAL  GOVERNMENTS,  1951-63 


(percentages) 
Protection 
Sanitation        to 

Highways  and  persons  General 

and  waste  and  govern- 

Year              Education     roads  removal  property  ment  Health 

1945 27.5            16.1  6.4  14.6  11.5  8.8 

1946-1950  not  available 

1951 37.9            12.3  7.4  16.1  6.1  4.7 

1952 40.2            12.9  6.4  12.7  6.8  5.5 

1953 38.1            13.4  8.5  12.2  7.1  5.3 

1954 31.9            14.1  18.2  11.2  6.2  5.1 

1955 32.3            19.3  10.6  13  1  7.2  4.2 

1956 33.0            16.7  12.2  12.0  7.7  4.5 

1957 32.8            21.8  9.2  11.1  6.6  4.3 

1958 31.0            21.9  9.5  11.8  7.0  3.8 

1959 32.2            22.0  9.4  11.6  6.7  3.0 

1960 33.0            20.3  9.1  11.0  6.5  3.4 

1961 33.3            17.6  11.4  11.9  6.1  3.1 

1962 31.7            19.6  9.8  11.7  6.2  3.7 

1963 32.7            19.0  10.1  11.5  7.0  2.0 


Deficits 
of 
municipal 
Social       Debt       enter-     Miscel- 
welfare    charges     prises     laneous 


4.2 


4.7 


5.6 


Total 


100.0 


4.2 

3.4 

.3 

7.6 

100.0 

4.0 

3.7 

.5 

7.3 

100.0 

3.8 

4.2 

.4 

7.0 

100.0 

3.4 

4.0 

.3 

5.6 

100.0 

3.5 

4.1 

.3 

5.4 

100.0 

3.4 

4.5 

.7 

5.3 

100.0 

2.7 

5.2 

.3 

6.0 

100.0 

3.0 

5.3 

.4 

6.3 

100.0 

2.7 

5.6 

.4 

6.4 

100.0 

2.7 

6.1 

1.2 

6.7 

100.0 

2.6 

6.8 

1.1 

6.1 

100.0 

2.4 

6.8 

1.2 

6.9 

100.0 

2.3 

7.2 

1.4 

6.8 

100.0 

Source:  Table  4:10. 


129 


The  Ontario  Setting 


J 

<; 

u 

o 

1^ 

fn 

o 

w 

U 

O 

ti 

& 

2 

H 

< 

Q 

H 

2; 

C^ 

Z 

U 

-^ 

O 

s 

o 

hJ 

5§ 

w 

^ 

rt 

H 

u 

w 

g 

?: 

w 

> 

o 

o 

o 

b 

O 

o 

h 

-»: 
o 


»*H,^      CO 

O  01  ^ 
-.S--E 

"5  o  a 


Q  « 


a  ^ 


lis. 

S  t^  o 
V  a;  ^ 


5  &  S 

OS  C  £ 
M  oj 


05  00  0      ■*f~.'^.'*.0,     00'<J"_Oi_C0 

COXN     0500SCD05     w  CD  c^i  ^ 
•^■"jico    cOt^oooiO_    e^(Niqco_ 


^■^^     i-H-^WC^CO     OOC^iO 


iC— "(s."   o<o"oO'-;o    to  "So  a 


00*01  m"    co"t^"oc'oo'c5"    O5co"oo"r-r 
S2n     <NINiNW'l<     i5.iSiOto 


«?IS    o '*!<".  9.".    »S-Hoq 

«^"t-i"rrr     ■<*' I^  O  X  »C     ^OoToi" 
2^55     lN<Nm<N<N     MMtOM 


„fZS     0_iN_0t~._O     «OOCD 


■*«DIM     2Se22?S     Oll^-^OI 


^~  — CD  !2!S2:;?2  cccococ^ 

k  — -S!  Z!;2S^S  o>"3co"5 

oorto  ''.'^.°'*'^.  o-;Ooqc<3 

^f^e^  r^  c*3  ^  00 1^  -^'ococo 

c3mS  "flt-CDCCt-  xSoS 


<»CD"rH"     223IS5S     OCNiOOJ' 

S?.o   S222S52   >o-<».ooo> 


•"•"fl  •*  J?  S  S  S  £  w.  w-  w-  — 

•-«  CD  CO    Ci-^oco^    r^  Tf  ^  CD 

<N"e>i"t-"  r^gsss  <»'-"- 2 


OiOiOi- 


o»ao>  22222  SSSo 


C3J3 

S-s 


Q5 


■g.« 


Cj  3 


^.1^ 


•5<i  * 
"S—  <s 

§  n!  a 

^    Q,  (U 


■~j^  a 

<s  o  o 

■SCI" 


•2  '"'2 

'iScD  B 

§2  o- 


5SS  -5 

--,^    .  .2- 
g  o"  o    m   S 

«  fc  i  "S  S 

.2-s  g  cs  5 

^■2  •;    o  g 

08  ■"  O  es 

o  ft*  *^    c8  aj 

.E   _  o   u  ,a 

S  c  >,  *?  '^ 

«)  «  ♦ 


5  H 


O  '^ 

o  ^ 

5  (a 

s  s 

^g 

1^ 

go 

o  t;:; 

^9 

6  z 
pa  H 

CO  *^ 

s^ 

Og 

Z  O 

U  CO 
(JJ  O 
W  tf 


°a.l 

CO  a  S) 
QEg 


OS 


.3  * 

CO  ^ 


28 
^  a 
a  be 


HI 


•2g§. 
«aa 
««  a 

d 
"^■S  OS 

fls  a  ^ 

CO  OS 


d  OS 

*  2 


W§ 


ppo  ooooo  oooo 
oo5  ooooo  oooo 


pcoco    nracooix    c^cooooo 


rrnm    poioinccco    ojoooooi 
odd   ddddd   dddd 


iNOt-    oqcoMop    t-<>opoq 
^  ^  CO    CO  CO  CO  ^  ^    ^  ^  CO  CO 


COINCO     U5CD'>l>O>C0     CDTfcD' 

■««'*>■*    eocococNC^    Noici. 


ph-^    e^ •»»" t~. 00 1»    >ii<ppp 
dcDoi    doiodoooo    oooioor^ 


pt>.t>;      COCOCl'-'P      pt>;Oqp 


ppeo    c^cot»T)<p    cDC<t>.p 
ujuicd    dod'H^^    doioooo 


i-Hi-cO>     T)<Of  0>«     r^OT(<p 


•o»o>o      __-- 

OidOi    Oi  Oi  a  a  Oi    moiOi  d 


lO  *C  »0  lO  *0      CD  CD  CD  CD 


^1 

^ 


^^ 


■*  a  a 
•S-l 

g»5 


130 


Chapter  4:  Appendix 

Table  4:14 
PROVINCE  OF  ONTARIO 

COMBINED  PROVINCIAL  AND  LOCAL  NET  GENERAL  EXPENDITURE  AND 
PROVINCIAL  DOMESTIC  PRODUCT.  ONTARIO  AND  REST  OF  CANADA,  1945-62 


Year 


1945 

252,734 

1946 

326,635 

1947 

369,354 

1948 

455,023 

1949 

474,615 

1950 

518,454 

1951 

627,722 

1952 

707,992 

1953 

759,739 

1954 

907,975 

1955 

1,014,089 

1956 

1,137,633 

1957 

1,330,627 

1958 

1,443,863 

1959 

1,689,090 

1960 

1,834,405 

1961 

1,959,369 

1962 

2,180,839 

(1)  (2) 

Provincial  and  local 

net  general  expenditure 

Ontario  Rest  of  Canada 

(thousands  of  dollars) 


466,832 
575,500 
725,000 
871,524 
947,231 

1,036,527 
1,210,749 
1,384,442 
1,480,307 
1,665,573 

1,825,252 
2,041,256 
2,298,335 
2,444,596 
2,771,230 


(3) 


(4) 


Provincial  domestic  product 
Ontario       Rest  of  Canada 
(millions  of  dollars) 


3,145,854 
3,347,435 
3,662,402 


4,331 
4,150 
4,591 
5,260 
5,776 

6,478 
7,364 
8,281 
8,731 
8,920 

9,799 
10,784 
11,717 
12,047 
12.844 

13,150 
13,670 
14,605 


6,473 
6,641 
7,266 
8,439 
9,109 

9,980 
11,762 
13,063 
13,475 
13,293 

14,527 
16,405 
16,581 
16.998 
18,054 

19,186 
19,661 
21,245 


(1)  as  a 

percentage 

of  (3) 

5.8 
7.9 
8.0 
8.7 
8.2 

8.0 
8.5 
8.5 
8.7 
10.2 

10.3 
10.5 
11.4 
12.0 
13.2 

13.9 
14.3 
14.9 


(2)  as  a 

percentage 

of  (4) 

7.2 

8.7 

9.9 
10.3 
10.4 

10.4 
10.3 
10.6 
11.0 
12.5 

12.6 
12.4 
13.9 
14.4 
15.3 

16.4 
17.0 
17.2 


Source:  Canada,  Dominion  Bureau  of  Statistics,  Historical  Review,  Financial  Statistics  of  Governments  in  Canada,  1 95£-6£; 
NatioTuU  Accounts,  1926-56,  1963;  and  datasuppliedbythe  Ontario  Department  of  Economics  and  Development. 


Table  4:15 
PROVINCE  OF  ONTARIO 

COMBINED  PROVINCIAL  AND  LOCAL  NET  GENERAL  EXPENDITURE 
AND  PERSONAL  INCOME,  BY  PROVINCE,  1952  AND  1962 


Province 


British  Columbia 

Alberta 

Saskatchewan 

Manitoba 

Ontario 

Quebec 

New  Brunswick 

Nova  Scotia 

Prince  Edward  Island. 
Newfoundland 

All  Provinces 2,091,438 


1952 


(thousands  of  dollars) 


1962 


Net  general 
expenditure 

Personal 
income 

(1)  as  a 

percentage 

of  (2) 

(3) 

Net  general 
expenditure 

(4) 

Personal 
income 

(5) 

(3)  as  a 

percentage 

of  (4) 

(1) 

(2) 

(6) 

237,827 

1,728,000 

13.8 

581.034 

3,112,000 

18.7 

188,247 

1,328,000 

14.2 

491,053 

2,307,000 

21.3 

133,873 

1,209,000 

11  1 

309,042 

1.571,000 

19.7 

90,954 

934,000 

9.7 

276,676 

1,563,000 

17.7 

707,992 

6,749,000 

10.5 

2,180,83y 

12,227,000 

17.8 

553,536 

4,152,000 

13.3 

1,541,898 

7,749,000 

19.9 

66,887 

406,000 

16.5 

144,280 

672,000 

21.5 

72,301 

553,000 

13.1 

172,201 

925,000 

18.6 

8,880 

71,000 

12.5 

30,280 

109,000 

27.8 

30,941 

219,000 

14.1 

106,303 

460,000 

23.1 

5,833,606 


30,695,000 


19.0 


Source:  Canada,  Dominion  Bureau  of  Statistics,  Historical  Review,  Financial  Statistics  of  Governments  in  Canada, 
1962-62;    National  Accounts,  1926-1956,  1963. 


131 


The  Ontario  Setting 

Table  4:16 

PROVINCE  OF  ONTARIO 

COMBINED  PROVINCIAL  AND  LOCAL  NET  GENERAL  EXPENDITURE 
PER  CAPITA,  BY  PROVINCE.  1952  AND  1962 

(dollars) 
Province  1952  1962 

British  Columbia 197.37  350.23 

Alberta 193.47  358.43 

Saskatchewan 158.81  332.30 

Manitoba 113.98  295.91 

Ontario 147.87  343.87 

Quebec 132.62  287.35 

New  Brunswick 127.16  237.69 

Nova  Scotia 110.72  230.83 

Prince  Edward  Island 88.80  285.66 

Newfoundland 82.73  226.18 

All  Provinces 144.90  314.80 

All  Provinces,  excluding  Ontario 143.42  299.68 

Source:    Canada,  Dominion  Bureau  of  Statistics,  Historical  Review,  Financial  Statistics  of  Governments  in  Canada, 
196£-6e;  National  Accounts,  19H6-1966,  1963. 


132 


Chapter  4:  Appendix 


•^   TO    C 

o  b  u 


o 

< 

iz; 
O 

o 

u 

S  o 


b  a 
<u  o: 
Pi 


CD       COIM<D'*t~       T)iOS<D050       00"-<0C<5       COO)    CO  Ol    t)<       0—<MC^tO       •>J<(No> 


00     rH  oo_  •^  (M_  o_     •-<_  eo_  (»  to  Tf<_ 
<o     oo"  m"  .-h  00  oo"     h-"  00  <n"  i-T  ir> 

00       OOC'-iOr-i       ^NTt<05-H 


>ra  t^  cv)   _   , 

lO   C^l    CO    lO    Oi 

00  lo  ci  Oi  c^"     05  t>r  o>«-^ 

<N    CO    O    ■^    1^       Oi   <N    h-OJ 

cjNcococo     co-^Tjiio 


03    CD    00-^    t^        t^CT>»0»-iCO        TJ^OIX 


oeoNOJt^     C005M 


IM  cD-^CO-*eO        05t^>-i000 

<3>  Ol-^OCOOIN       —    ■-    — 

t^  00  -fl",^  •*   t>;^  o_ 

o"  o"  o"  -H  ■*"  o" 

,-1  rt     rt     — (     .-H     M 


.-..^„      ,oo>(5u;co     co-*NOo> 

CC    CD   N    -^    t>.  <0_  CO_  05   O    CD 

r-Toosoi'-^  cocoioo^co 

(MIN,_i,_,CV)  NC0C0CO-* 


^^,,^w-  lOCOiOcDOO  t-iuOcD 

^  r:;  S?*"  '^  cDot^oot^  o^oit^ 

iq  oo_  ocD  (M  oqcNOcDc;  ocdco 

»ot^<Nt^co  cDOiiOi-To)  coo'co 

■^    ■*    lOiO   CD  COCOt^OOoO  O"^-* 


-Ji    >0       00    00   <M   -H 


^        -  05   <N    "-lO    00       CDCOt^Oi-H       C3)0000 

--_^-—        t^lNiONCO        ^CDCDOO.-!       COOO)-*(N        ScOOO 

t>;"5iM_05O5     O)oqcooq^_     oo-i<  -ho  lO     r-cocorHii     ^:ooi2 

lO   ^'  i-<  .-T  i-H  CO   (N  N*  1(5"  tC  U5   Tj<"  tC  rH  oJ  o   lO  lO  oTrH  CO   CO  r-T  p"  "S"" 

CD  CD 


lO  <-i  CD  CD  CO 


N  >-l  N   N  N  (NCO  CO   CO  CO  m 


CO  00  (N 


00-HOOira      cot-i-ioot»      cDo)cD'>j<oo      coo  ooeo  i-h      --iioooeo      coc-qh~ 

r»^^.    ►^.^        -«nn^i-.^        CDcDt^iCJO        -^JtOt^iOOS        CD-Ht^^(D        mSS 


O  CO  (M  t^  lO 
^_  IN  CO_  ■*  O 
im"  (N    (N    (N    (N 


^.     00     C^      -.f     -H 

CD   0_  C^    CD    O 
rt"  of  ■-("  (N    CO 


o_  .-I  io_  r^  ■* 
eo"  Tj<"  ui  T}("  •^" 


>. 

i 

e 

1 

> 

(N'-iO'^"-i       CDINOOCD       ^OCOCO 


C0OJINt)<cD       (N'^'l'CDTfi 


0_  IN    CD'O    IN 
"5   t>."  00"o"  (X 


O    O    t^lN    N 


CO  .-i_  f< 
tri  •*  co" 


■<*^  O  -^  t^  CO  t^ 

3!  "^  ■*  CO  IN  lo 

_  O    WD  O  CD  ^    -H 

CO  h-  o  CO  IN      CO  Tji  Ti>co  Tt<      CO  uD  h-"  lo"  rC  co"  oo"  oT 


CD    CD    t^    .-1 


C^COCOr-UD  -^OOCDWCN  NincO'^-H  COOOO«5CO  ^OCD 

1-.--1-.       t>.C3>OlOO"D  t>.rtiO<NcD  CDCO-*00CO  (Ni-HPlt-O  i-iCvlOO 

M^   ^_  i_<  00_  1-H  1-1   c^  KD  o>  <N  CD  00  CD  ■*  05  IN  CD_  00_  (>;■*  ■*  00_  CO  ira  1-H  tj"  lO  t>.  O 

t~     oo"  Oi  o"  t~^  03     os"  02  IN  Ti<"  T)<"  CO  cr"  c"  co"  lo  t-"  os  -^'t^  ■-<"  o>"  .-H  co"  c^"  lo  o"  co"  "i 

.-lrt.-H  .-(.-INC^C^  C^CO'>J<-*'0  iracOcDCDt~  OOOOOO 


o     ooouDo     t^coooo     .-H^coiraai 


05  o  CO  r-  o 


O  CO  »-H  03  CO 

00  t^_  05  c^_  c^_ 

oo"  ■«<'  co"  oo"  o> 


lO  t>.  o_ 

O  1^'  oS   <r  CO 


l^  CO  »0  CD  lO 
CO  »-*"  cd"cO  CO 


■ii-ii-HIN        1-llNINCOCO        T1ITJ<'>J<'>}<-<1<        Tj-iO    mco    t- 


ooooo  ooo 

cjoooo  ooo 

03CD»0*Oi-t  ooo 
co"  o"  in"  r-T  tC 


OSCO        ,-iCOCOO)CO         C^T}<00-*CO 


DOO-HCDOO       C0t^OOr>-       00OIN0005       WiOOINCO       OOcDCO'OO  0)0 

-—         —     -  .-.--,—      -.     ..  -^^_*      lo^-t^coi-H      ^icocoicD  ooo 

CO_    0C_    roiO     O)         r-<_CDr-<— <CO  —CO 

ci  CO  c^"oo  »o     c^"  r^  lo  cc"  CO  i-h"  m" 

"   ■     '"  c^  CO 


lO        i-(    CD    CO    O)    1-* 

00       UDcDI^OOi       -  -,      .  -       _  --    

•-^       C^WC^C^t-t       T-iC^ICOTfiO       40CDt^t>>X       OiO    ^CO 


o  ""i  IN  -^  in 

00  -*  -H  t>r  in" 


"D    lO    to    t~    00 


"D       (NINCO-^i)'       ^iOtJiOC^       OOOi-icO-h  t>.t>.   00  "C   <-* 

y-t       <N.-H(N00O5       t^cOC4->)<00       OOC0C0"D  ■^•<j<iO<35i-l 

c^     oot-*cDXco     r>-050^*^*     c^co'-ico-**'  t^co^ocot^ 

CD      CDodciOOO)       odoOoT-TfO       ■^jTcOTtTcOTji"  c^oo"o*c^oo 

•^        i-l(NC^iNC^        (NINC^TfCO        cOt^OCMCO  '^COCOIN'* 

i-H     rl  .-I     .-.     .-H  IN     IN 


Oi-HNco^w     uDcor^xo)     OrHC^co^     ^^  t^oo  o 


Soo  ic  00 
co_  oj  Tf 

"J    O)    co"  t>^  Tit"       oo"   Tj<"  O" 

opoioocor^      cscoc^ 

C^C^CaCOCO       ■*U5CD 


T}<Tj<Tl<-*t''^        iOiO>OVOO 


05        050100501        CJ)O5O5C7)05        050)05050 


0505C35C3505        050505 


'Sen 


-     K    £ 


=  ^  H 


133 


The  Ontario  Setting 


H 

2: 

> 
O 
O 

O 

> 
O 

O     a, 


< 

o 

o 

w 
u 

> 
o 

Ql, 


"a  « 


12  S  S 

O   C.2 

Is." 


O  0] 

o 


4/    IS 


ooqqo  ppppq 
odoo'o  ooooo 
ooooo   ooooo 


ooooo 
dodod 


ooooo 


iO^HTf4^^i-4    •^tOCiC^t^         ^C^Oit^Oi 

oodcidd   dN'-''-''-'   .-i>-<ddd 


•<J<  to  0>  ^  ■>*"        ratOOO^N        Wt^OOOOM 


00^C0t*O        u^  ^t*  Oi  ?D  »C        00»OCO^        eOCOf-HOOCO        o^^.-;<ocD        -^  CO  ^^ 
eOTi'-'i'Tit'.ii       •^■^■^nri       roc<5co^co       poc^conin       pic^N'^.-i       ,-i^i-i 


d  00  00  to  t^ 


■^•"i;  00  00  00 


05  CO  noo 
CO  o>o>ooao 


>ot^co       ao>o^> 


U500> 


W^f^OOJ         T-HC0030N         oo"5^^00CO         t^poOCOOs        OppOOp         ^HiO^^ 

^doidcD      ddocdoo      iN^ioTrcsc^      ,-ic^i-H^f^      ^doooos      oioo^ 


i-i  00  p  t>- -.1; 

-.—  ,_._         cDOO-i'O'-* 


0'-^*ddo       T**????^?? 


cocop^p      o»<dP 


(NMC^NM  c<C^r<C<IN         CINN— 1>-I  .-c,-.'-' 


t-tt^^m'-i       t^Mopt-.       (Oint^pt-       pwP 
o6o6"-<"id       "pc^^t;??       dd^^^       "liooJS 


rt       J-hcsc^(NO       (nc-knmcvi       NNcocoro       rocorocoeo       -tr-vnnc 


g   S55i55:    ^^^55   s:;;ss?s   s:§t;?ss    gssss    S|| 


^  P=! 


M  (a 


^f 


134 


Chapter  4:  Appendix 

Table  4:19 

PROVINCE  OF  ONTARIO 

PROVINCIAL  GOVERNMENT  RECEIPTS  FROM  THE  GOVERNMENT  OF  CANADA 
FOR  SHARED-COST  PROGRAMS  AND  GRANTS-IN-AID,  1939-64 


Fiscal 
year 


(thousands  of  dollars) 
Ordinary  Capital 


Total 


1939 17,014 

1940 17,490 

1941 13,521 

1942 12,981 

1943 12,851 

1944 12,953 

1945 14,261 

1946 .  " 16,230 

1947 19,571 

1948 21,615 

1949." 23,176 

1950 34,545 

1951 36,699 

1952 31,504 

1953 15,888 

1954 14,387 

1955 16,410 

1956 19,226 

1957 19,289 

1958 22,594 

1959 49,560 

1960 1 18,850 

1961 132,050 

1962 160,611 

1963 190,926 

1964 210,368 


17.014 

69 
102 

17,490 
13,521 
12,981 
12,920 
13,055 

14,261 
16,230 
19,571 
21,615 
23,176 

2,790 
7,009 
4,923 
3,253 

34,545 
39,489 
38,513 
20,811 
17,640 

6,684 

3,651 

6,157 

13,970 

19,283 

23,094 
22,877 
25,446 
36,564 
68,843 

21,571 
22,583 
26,452 
130,908 
71,873 

140,421 
154,633 
187,063 
321,834 
282,241 

Source:  Canada,  Dominion  Bureau  of  Statistics,  Financial  Statistics  of  Provincial  Governments,  1941-1962.  Ontario, 
Public  Accounts,  1939-1964.  Canada,  Department  of  Finance,  Federal-Provincial  Conditional  Grant  and  Shared-Cost 
Programs,  1962. 

Table  4:20 

PROVINCE  OF  ONTARIO 

GROSS  MONEY  REVENUES  OF  PROVINCIAL  GOVERNMENT, 
MUNICIPALITIES  AND  SCHOOL  BOARDS,  1939-64 


(thousands  of  dollars) 

Provincial 

Year  government*     Municipalities        School  boards 

1939 103,857  109,811  57,795 

1940 105,663  105,687  59,777 

1941 117,323  99,857  59,833 

1942 124,477  95,390  60,460 

1943 121,134  94,927  62,795 

1944 131,152  100,495  66,466 

1945 131,385  106,664  63,413 

1946 144,599  119,353  67,734 

1947 162,447  120,974  77,607 

1948 213,314  138,728  93,534 

1949 238,646  156,205  107,843 

1950 263,095  170,875  118,242 

1951 304,761  196,235  141,667 

1952 340,834  223,492  156,122 

1953 370,311  237,400  180,290 

1954 390,613  265,714  203,383 

1955 422,487  295,762  234,397 

1956 450,846  326,889  260,577 

1957 505,229  372,839  298,140 

1958 628,413  415,725  346,488 

1959 711,217  459,334  395,645 

1960 842,891  507,758  436,280 

1961 894,024  545,897  487,573 

1962 1,012,415  590,143  545,129 

1963 1,315,446  632,457  596,307 

1964 1,361,377 


Indexes  (1939=100) 


Source:  Tables  4:17,  4:19,  4:24  and  4:25. 
*Fiscal  years  ending  March  31. 


Provincial 

government 

Municipalities  School  boards 

100.0 

100.0 

100.0 

101.7 

96.2 

103.4 

113.0 

90.9 

103.5 

119.9 

86.9 

104.6 

116.6 

86.4 

108.7 

126.3 

91.5 

115.0 

126.5 

97.1 

109.7 

139.2 

108.7 

117.2 

156.4 

110.2 

134.3 

205.4 

126.3 

161.8 

229.8 

142.2 

186.6 

253.3 

155.6 

204.6 

293.4 

178.7 

245.1 

328.2 

203.5 

270.1 

356.6 

216.2 

311.9 

376.1 

242.0 

351.9 

406.8 

269.3 

405.6 

434.1 

297.7 

450.9 

486.5 

339.6 

515.9 

605.1 

378.6 

599.5 

684.8 

418.3 

684.6 

811.6 

462.4 

754.9 

860.8 

497.1 

843.6 

974.8 

537.4 

943.2 

1,266.6 

576.0 

1,031.8 

1,310.8 

135 


The  Ontario  Setting 


Table  4:21 

PROVINCE  OF  ONTARIO 

NET  MONEY  REVENUES  OF  PROVINCIAL  GOVERNMENT, 

MUNICIPALITIES  AND  SCHOOL  BOARDS,  1939-64 


(thousands  of  dollars) 

Indexes  (1939  = 

100) 

Year 

Provincial 
government* 

83,902 

Municipalities 
95,305 

School  boards 

Provincial 
government 

Municipalities 
100.0 

School  boards 

1939 

49,402 

100.0 

100.0 

1940 
1941 
1942 
1943 
1944 

85,232 
100,861 
108,360 
105,040 
114,942 

93,882 
90,713 
86,916 
87,126 
91,450 

50.610 
49,822 
50,270 
52,148 
55.002 

101.6 
120.2 
129.2 
125.2 
137.0 

98.5 
95.2 
91.2 
91.4 
96.0 

102.4 
100.9 
101.8 
105.6 
111.3 

1945 
1946 
1947 
1948 
1949 

113,969 
125,214 
139.721 
188.544 
212.315 

97,674 
108,136 
104,848 
114,679 
127,596 

34,485 
37,125 
46,156 
56,407 
65,907 

135.8 
1492 
166.5 
224.7 
253.1 

102.5 
113.5 
110.0 
120.3 
133.9 

69.8 

75.1 

93.4 

114.2 

133.4 

1950 
1951 
1952 
1953 
1954 

225.395 
261.631 
298,680 
345,859 
369,332 

139,427 
160,100 
181,993 
193,805 
209.351 

71,462 
90,162 
101,455 
118,154 
131,364 

268.6 
311.8 
356.0 
412.2 
440.2 

146.3 
168.0 
191.0 
203.4 
219.7 

144.7 
182.5 
205.4 
239.2 
265  9 

1955 
1956 
1957 
1958 
1959 

395,752 
424,328 
476,142 
588,208 
638,733 

228,844 
253,846 
281.795 
309,281 
336,859 

152,787 
176,419 
197,178 
212,795 
245,488 

471.7 
505.7 
567.5 
701.1 
761.3 

240.1 
266.4 
295.7 
324.5 
353.5 

309.3 
357.1 
399.1 
430.7 
496.9 

1960 
1961 
1962 
1963 
1964 

698,829 
735,750 
820,728 
988,988 
1,074,512 

372,269 
401,841 
434,587 
466,920 

275,490 
303,686 
340,713 
361,523 

832.9 

876.9 

978.2 

1,178.7 

1,280.7 

390.6 
421.6 
456.0 
489.9 

557.6 
614.7 
689.7 
731.8 

Source:  Ontario,  Public  Accounts,  1939-1964,  and  Tables  4:24  and  4:25. 
*Fiscal  years  ending  March  31. 


Table  4:22 

PROVINCE  OF  ONTARIO 

NET  REAL  REVENUES  OF  PROVINCIAL  GOVERNMENT, 
MUNICIPALITIES  AND  SCHOOL  BOARDS,  1939-64 


(thousands  of  1949  dollars) 

Indexes  (1939  = 

100) 

Year 

Provincial 
government* 

Municipalities 
160,150 

School  boards 

Provincial 
government 

100.0 

Municipalities 

School  boards 

1939 

140,351 

83,098 

100.0 

100.0 

1940 
1941 
1942 
1943 
1944 

140,810 
158,836 
161,780 
146,765 
156,002 

149,684 
138,345 
122,884 
119,025 
120,281 

81,002 
76,391 
70,893 
71,279 
72,096 

100.3 
113.2 
115.3 
104.6 
111.2 

93.5 
86.4 
76.7 
74.3 
75.1 

97.5 
91.9 
85.3 
85.8 
86.8 

1945 
1946 
1947 
1948 
1949 

148,765 
158,962 
17.5,573 
218,071 
220,771 

124,791 
138,867 
125,057 
118.360 
127,596 

43,785 
47,553 
55,052 
59,370 
65,907 

106.0 
113.3 
125.1 
155.4 
157.3 

77.9 
86.7 
78.1 
73.9 
79.7 

52.7 
57.2 
66.2 
71.4 
79.3 

1950 
1951 
1952 
1953 
1954 

219,576 
244,424 
251,584 
282,726 
292,935 

133,602 
137,815 
150,482 
155,342 
162,919 

68,300 
77,492 
83,591 
94,425 
102,149 

156.4 
174.2 
179.3 
201.4 
208.7 

83.4 
86.1 
94.0 
97.0 
101.7 

82.2 
93.3 
1006 
113.6 
122.9 

1955 
1956 
1957 
1958 
1959 

305,907 
321,193 
342,277 
402,111 
429,285 

174,066 
183,813 
194,866 
215,527 
227,854 

115,538 
126,966 
135,415 
145,640 
162,683 

218.0 
228.8 
243.9 
286.5 
305.9 

108.7 
114.8 
121.7 
134.6 
142.3 

139.0 
152.8 
163.0 
175.3 
195.8 

1960 
1961 
1962 
1963 
1964 

4  54.. 346 
461.806 
517.124 
586.032 
622,689 

248,312 
269,855 
279,208 
286,436 

178,773 
192,853 
207,360 
211.590 

323.7 
329.0 
368.5 
417.5 
443.7 

155.0 
168.5 
174.3 
178.9 

215.1 
232.1 
249.5 
254.6 

Source:  Table  4:21. 

♦Fiscal  years  ending  March  31. 


136 


Chapter  4:  Appendix 


Table  4:23 

PROVINCE  OF  ONTARIO 

NET  REAL  PER-CAPITA  REVENUES  OF  PROVINCIAL  GOVERNMENT, 
MUNICIPALITIES  AND  SCHOOL  BOARDS,  1939-64 


(1949  dollars) 

Indexes  (1939  =  100) 

Provincial 

Provincial 

Year 
1939 

government* 
38.22 

Municipalities 
43.19 

School  boards 

government 
100.0 

Municipalities 
100.0 

School  boards 

22.41 

100.0 

1940 

37.97 

39.95 

21.62 

99.3 

92.5 

96.5 

1941 

42.39 

36.52 

20.17 

110.9 

84.6 

90.0 

1942 

42.71 

31.64 

18.25 

111.7 

73.3 

81.4 

1943 

37.79 

30.40 

18.21 

9S.9 

70.4 

81.3 

1944 

39.85 

30.35 

18.19 

104.3 

70.3 

81.2 

1945 

37.54 

31.20 

10.95 

98.2 

72.2 

48.9 

1946  . 

39.74 

33.93 

11.62 

104.0 

78.6 

51.9 

1947 

42.90 

29.95 

13.18 

112.2 

69.3 

58.8 

1948 

52.22 

27.69 

13.89 

136.6 

64.1 

62.0 

1949 

51.64 

29.14 

15.05 

135.1 

67.5 

67.2 

1950 

50.15 

29.88 

15.28 

131.2 

69.2 

68.2 

1951 

54.67 

29.97 

16.85 

143.0 

69.4 

75.2 

1952 

54.72 

31.43 

17.46 

143.2 

72.8 

77.9 

1953 

59.05 

31.44 

19.11 

154.5 

72.8 

85.3 

1954 

59.29 

31.85 

19.97 

155.1 

73.7 

89  1 

1955 

59.81 

33.05 

21.94 

156.5 

76.5 

97.9 

1956 

60.99 

34.01 

23.49 

159.6 

78.7 

104.8 

1957 

63.33 

34.58 

24.03 

165.7 

80.1 

107.2 

1958 

7135 

37.03 

25.02 

186.7 

85.7 

111.6 

1959 

73.75 

38.17 

27.25 

193.0 

88.4 

121.6 

1960 

76.12 

40.63 

29.25 

199.2 

94.1 

130.5 

1961 

75.57 

43.27 

30.93 

197.7 

100.2 

138.0 

1962 

82.93 

44.03 

32.70 

217.0 

101.9 

145.9 

1963 

92.40 

44.42 

32.81 

241.8 

102.8 

146.4 

1964 

96.57 

252.7 

Source:  Tables  4:21  and  4:22. 
♦Fiscal  years  ending  March  31. 


Table  4:24 

PROVINCE  OF  ONTARIO 

CURRENT  REVENUES  OF  MUNICIPALITIES,  1939-63 


(thousands  of  dollars) 


percentage  distribution 


Year 


1939. 

1940. 
1941. 
1942. 
1943. 
1944. 

1945. 
1946. 
1947. 
1948. 
1949. 

1950. 
1951. 
1952. 
1953. 
1954. 

1955. 
1956. 
1957. 
1958. 
1959. 

1960. 
1961. 
1962. 
1963. 


Total 
grants 

14,506 

11,805 
9.144 
8,474 
7,801 
9,045 

8,990 
11,217 
16,126 
24,049 
28,609 

31,448 
36,135 
41,499 
43,595 
56,363 

67,133 
73,043 
91,044 
106,444 
122,475 

135,489 
144,056 
155,556 
165,537 


Total 

municipal 

tax  levy 

84,327 

84,024 
80,675 
77,892 
77,609 
77,249 

83,469 
89,628 
89,222 
96,362 
108,526 

119,850 
139,897 
158,597 
167,112 
179,610 

194,395 
216,574 
243,118 
265,386 
291,049 


323,699 
350,212 
376,328 
404,284 


Other 
revenues 

10,978 

9,858 
10,038 
9,024 
9,517 
14,201 

14,205 
18,508 
15,626 
18,317 
19,070 

19,577 
20,203 
23,396 
26,693 
29,741 

34,234 
37,272 
38,677 
43,895 
45,810 


48,570 
51,629 
58,259 
62,636 


Total 

Total 

municipal 

Other 

grants 

tax  levy 
76.79 

revenues 

13.21 

10.00 

11.17 

79.50 

9.33 

9.16 

80.79 

10.05 

8.88 

81.66 

9.46 

8.22 

81.76 

10.02 

9.00 

76.87 

14.13 

8.43 

78.25 

13.32 

9.40 

75.09 

15.51 

13.33 

73.75 

12.92 

17.34 

69.46 

13.20 

18.31 

69.48 

12.21 

18.40 

70.14 

11.46 

18.41 

71.29 

10.30 

18.57 

70.96 

10.47 

18.36 

70.39 

11.25 

21.21 

67.60 

11.19 

22.70 

65.73 

11.57 

22.35 

66.25 

11.40 

24.42 

65.21 

10.37 

25.60 

63.84 

10.56 

26.66 

63.36 

9.98 

26.68 

63.75 

9.57 

26.39 

64.15 

9.46 

26.36 

63.77 

9.87 

26.17 

63.92 

9.91 

Source:  Ontario,  Department  of  Municipal  Affairs,  Annual  Report  of  Municipal  Statistics,  1939-1963. 

137 


The  Ontario  Setting 


Table  4:25 

PROVINCE  OF  ONTARIO 

CURRENT  REVENUES  OF  SCHOOL  BOARDS.  1939-63 


(thousands  of  dollars) 


Year 

Total 
grants 

Total 
school 
tax  levy 

39.298 

Other 
revenues 

1939 

8.393 

10,104 

1940 

1941 

1942 

1943 

1944 

9.167 
10.011 
10.190 
10,647 
11.464 

40,288 
40,852 
41,420 
43,023 
43,502 

10.322 
8,970 
8,850 
9,125 

11,500 

1945 

1946 

1947 

1948 

1949 

28.928 
30,609 
31,451 
.  .  .            37.127 
41.936 

34,485 
37,125 
46,156 
52,450 
61,432 

N.A. 
N.A. 
N.A. 
3,957 
4,475 

1950 

1951 

1952 

1953 

1954 

46,780 
51.505 
54.667 
62,136 
72.019 

68,555 

86,386 

101,455 

112,862 

126,509 

2,907 
3,776 

N.A. 
5,292 
4.855 

1955 

1956 

1957 

1958 

1959 

81,610 

84,158 

100.962 

133,693 

150,157 

141,879 
165,797 
188,394 
200,442 
234,538 

10,908 
10,622 
8,784 
12,353 
10,950 

1960 

1961 

1962 

1963 

160.790 
183,887 
204,416 
234,787 

263,196 
291,098 
313,679 
341,611 

12,294 
12,588 
27,034 
19,909 

percentage  distribution 


Total 

Total 

school 

Other 

grants 

tax  levy 
68.00 

revenues 

14.52 

17.48 

15.33 

67.40 

17.27 

16.73 

68.28 

14.99 

16.85 

68.51 

14.64 

16.96 

68.51 

14.53 

17.25 

65.45 

17.30 

45.62 

54.38 



45.19 

54.81 

. — 

40.53 

59.47 

— 

39.69 

56.08 

4.23 

38.89 

56.96 

4.15 

39.56 

57.98 

2.46 

36.36 

60.98 

2.66 

35.02 

64.98 

— 

34.46 

62.60 

2.94 

35.41 

62.20 

2.39 

34.82 

60.53 

4.65 

32.30 

63.63 

4.07 

33.86 

63.19 

2.95 

38.59 

57.85 

3.56 

37.95 

59.28 

2.77 

36.85 

60.33 

2.82 

37.71 

59.70 

2.59 

37.50 

57.54 

4.96 

39.37 

57.29 

3.34 

Source:  Ontario,  Department  of  Education,  Report  of  the  Minister,  1939-1963;  Department  of  Municipal  Affairs, 
Annual  Report  of  Municipal  Statistics,  1939-1963. 


Table  4:26 

PROVINCE  OF  ONTARIO 

PROVINCIAL,  MUNICIPAL  AND  SCHOOL  BOARD  NET  REAL  REVENUES 

AS  A  PERCENTAGE  OF  REAL  PROVINCIAL 

DOMESTIC  PRODUCT,  1939-63 

(based  on  1949  dollars) 

Year 

(1) 

Provincial 
government* 

(2)                            (3) 
Municipalities       School  boards 

(4) 

Local 

(2-1-3) 

6.88% 

(5) 
Provincial 
and  local 

(1+4) 

1939 

3.97% 

4.53% 

2.35% 

10.85% 

1940 

1941 

1942 

1943 

1944 

3.45 

3.35 

3.01 

2.57 

2.71 

3.67 
2.92 
2.28 
2.08 
2.09 

1.99 
1.61 
1.32 
1.25 
1.25 

5.66 
4.53 
3.60 
3.33 
3.34 

9.11 
7.88 
6.61 
6.90 
6.05 

1945 

1946 

1947 

1948 

1949 

2.61 

2.98 

3.26 

3.98 

3.82 

2.19 
2.60 
2.32 
2.16 
2.21 

0.77 
0.89 
1.02 
1.08 
1.14 

2.96 
3.49 
3,34 
3.24 
3.35 

5.57 
6.47 
6.60 
7.22 
7.17 

1950 

1951 

1952 

1953 

1954 

3.49 

3.79 

3.64 

3.90 

4.05 

2,13 
2.14 
2.18 
2.14 
2.25 

1.09 
1.20 
1.21 
1.30 
1.41 

3.22 
3.34 
3.39 
3.44 
3.66 

6.71 
7.13 
7.03 
7.34 
7.71 

1955 

1956 

1957 

1958 

1959 

3.86 

3.83 

3.91 

4. .55 

4.69 

2.20 
2.19 
2.23 
2.44 
2.49 

1.46 
1.52 
1.55 
1  65 
1.78 

3.66 
3.71 
3.78 
4.09 
4.27 

7.52 
7.54 
7.68 
8.64 
8.96 

1960 

1961 

1962 

1963 

4.91 

4.86 

5.22 

5.64 

2.68 
2.84 
2.82 
2.75 

1.93 
2.03 
2.09 
2.04 

4.61 
4.87 
4.91 
4.79 

9.52 
9.73 
10.13 
10.43 

Source:  Tables  4:7  and  4:22. 
♦Fiscal  years  ending  March  31. 


138 


Chapter  4:  Appendix 


Table  4:27 
PROVINCE  OF  ONTARIO 

NET  CAPITAL  DEBT  OF  PROVINCIAL  GOVERNMENT  AND 
PROVINCIAL  DOMESTIC  PRODUCT,  1943-66 


Provincial  government  Net  capital  debt 

Fiscal  net  capital  debt  Provincial  domestic  product*  as  a  percentage  of 

year  (millions  of  dollars)  (billions  of  dollars)  domestic  product** 


1943 500  3.7  13.5 

1944 486  4.1  11.9 

1945 483  4.3  11.2 

1946 480  4.3  11.2 

1947 494  4.2  11.8 

1948 468  4.6  10.2 

1949 486  5.3  9.2 

1950 610  5.8  8.8 

1951 623  6.5  8.0 

1952 664  7.4  7.5 

1953 605  8.3  7.3 

1954 630  8.7  7.2 

1955 661  8.9  7.4 

1956 706  9.8  7.2 

1957 758  10.8  7.0 

1958 819  11.7  7.0 

1959 901  12.0  7.5 

1960 994  12.8  7.8 

1961 1,093  13.2  8.3 

1962 1,209  13.7  8.8 

1963 1,284  14.6  8.8 

1964 1,345  15  6  8.6 

1965 1,365  17.0  8.0 

1966 1,464  18.5  7.9 


Source:  Treasurer  of  Ontario,  Budget  Speech,  Table  A-6,  selected  years 

♦Figure  for  the  calendar  year  ending  on  the  preceding  Decembe 
Economics  and  Development. 

**Ratio  of  debt  of  fiscal  year  to  P.D.P.  of  nearest  calendar  year. 


♦Figure  for  the  calendar  year  ending  on  the  preceding  December  31.  Estimates  derived  by  Ontario  Department  of 
Economics  and  Development. 


139 


The  Ontario  Setting 


< 

H 
Z 

o 
o 
u 

> 

o 


9  Q 

■<  w 

U  OS 

s 


z-s 


2;-S 


i-H       CO       (N 


t~     in     e<5     CO 


^      <o      00 


lO       to       (O       N 


10  TO       N       00       00 
»-(       O       05       C       lO 

11  .1       ,-1       C^       TO 


l-H         lO         rt 


C3     lO     c^     00 


•-1  N       TO 


IN      in     TO     00 

-H        TO        00        Tji 
.-<        ,-1        ,-1       IN 


05       O^       Gi       CI       Oi 


^H  O       00       05       OS       TO 


05       C4       «0  .1 


lO       TO       lO       00 
O       *-^      O       05 


;_     ,-4     ^     C4 


TO      c^      Ol      TO      >5 
—I     o>     m     TO     «o 


TO       TO       N       IN 


05        lO        »0        X        05 


00       to       O       .-1 


lo     00     o> 


00     .-<     o» 


55         rH         ,-1         <N 


rl     ■■I'         .-1 


TOtO*-*  OWWTOOi 


.1       fi       N       TO 


s  s 


t~     r-         ^ 


TO       -H       TO 


t~  .-H        CM        lO       1-1        (N 


^         00     o     N     N      m 


d)     o>     c>     o) 


00      00      00      00      o> 


•O       to       t~  00 


TO       O       --I       TO       TO 

r^         r-t         lO         05         1^5 

Tjl       »0       lO       »o      to 


O)      to      to 


p  TO  "5  N  p  i-< 

40  ni  ni  to  00  00 

lO  to  TO  00  O  N 

t~  00  05  05  O  1-1 


(N       TO       TO       TO 


O  1-1  M  TO  •>* 
to  to  to  CO  to 
Oi       Oi       Oi       Oi       ^ 


0>       N        .1  to       00 


M       TO       00 

"3       t^       05  i-H       N       TO 


C<       00       --i 


00  lO  0>  "3  IN 
00  t^  to  to  O 
O       1-1       IN       TO       ira 


TO     in     to     05     (N 


U5  0>  to  TO  Tji 

•>t  CM  in  1-1  o> 

i-i_  iq  TO_  oo_  o> 

to  to  oo"  t~  m" 

CM  CI  TO  in  CM 


1*       0»       0>       TO  1-1 

CM       CM       TO       in  to 


<35       O       1-1       TO       CM 

^       OS       to       OS       OS 


1-1     in     00     CM 
in     in     in     to 


to  OS  in  o  CM 

OS  TO  OS  CM  O 

00  >n  in  TO  00 

i-T  o"  ^' 


in     CM      in 


--        CM        TO 


s      t> 


140 


Chapter 
5 


The  Incidence  of 
Government  Revenue 
and  Expenditure 


INTRODUCTION 

1.  In  this  chapter  we  present  a  summary  analysis  of  the  patterns  in  which 
the  burdens  of  taxation  and  the  benefits  of  government  expenditure  are  allocated 
among  Ontario  residents,  classified  according  to  size  of  income.  As  will  soon 
become  abundantly  clear,  the  task  of  determining  the  net  incidence  of  fiscal 
operations  is  fraught  with  difficulty,  particularly  since  we  have  attempted  to 
recognize  the  effects  of  the  revenue  and  expenditure  programs  of  all  levels  of 
government  within  Canada.  The  reader  is  therefore  cautioned  that  our  results 
should  be  regarded  not  as  empirically  verified  facts  but  as  logical  conclusions 
derived  from  the  application  of  appropriate  operating  assumptions  to  the  available 
data.^  To  the  extent  that  our  assumptions  are  reasonable,  our  study  of  tax  and 
expenditure  incidence  will  yield  results  that  approximate  the  actual  distribution  of 


'It  is  not  possible  within  the  confines  of  this  chapter  to  set  forth  the  multiplicity  of 
assumptions  that  must  be  made  to  undertake  an  empirical  investigation  of  this  sort. 
These  are  spelled  out  in  detail  in  the  supporting  monograph  by  J.  A.  Johnson,  The 
Incidence  of  Government  Revenues  and  Expenditures,  on  which  this  chapter  is  based; 
the  interested  reader  is  referred  to  this  source  for  a  more  extensive  treatment  of  the 
subject.  This  monograph  is  one  of  several  background  studies  being  published  by 
The   Ontario  Committee   on  Taxation. 

141 


Incidence  of  Government  Revenue  and  Expenditure 

tax  burdens  and  expenditure  benefits,  by  income  classes,  among  Ontario  taxpayers. 
Such  knowledge  is  fundamental  in  our  search  for  equity  in  the  Ontario  fiscal 
system. 

2.  In  the  light  of  the  difficulties  involved  in  any  analysis  of  fiscal  incidence, 
one  may  well  ask  why  such  a  study  has  been  undertaken.  The  answer  is  found  in 
the  basic  importance  of  determining  even  an  approximation  of  the  patterns  of  tax 
burdens  and  expenditure  benefits  among  Ontario  citizens.  Without  this  information, 
the  government's  continuing  task  of  improving  the  equity  and  the  economic  efficiency 
of  its  fiscal  operations  becomes  virtually  impossible.  On  the  other  hand,  an  aware- 
ness of  the  broad  incidence  of  its  revenue  and  expenditure  programs  will  enable  the 
government  to  formulate  policies  directed  to  greater  equity  and  to  a  more  efficient 
allocation  of  resources,  judged  in  accordance  with  democratically  determined 
objectives.  It  is  in  the  light  of  these  broad  objectives  that  the  Ontario  government 
must  make  decisions  relating  to  changes  in  the  aggregate  level  and  composition  of 
both  its  revenues  and  its  expenditures  and  to  the  consequent  changes  in  the 
distribution  of  income  among  the  residents  of  the  province. 

3.  Ideally,  our  study  should  measure,  as  among  these  income  groups,  welfare 
losses  and  gains  that  are  related  to  government  taxation  and  expenditure  programs. 
But  welfare  being  a  most  elusive  concept,  we  must  resort  to  what  is  at  best  an 
imperfect  measuring-rod,  namely  the  money  burdens  and  money  benefits  associated 
with  the  government's  fiscal  operations.  To  illustrate  the  difficulties  associated 
with  this  particular  yardstick  of  welfare,  two  points  may  be  emphasized.  The 
first  is  that  dollar  transfers  cannot  be  assumed  to  provide  a  quantitative  measure- 
ment of  underlying  welfare — the  public  expenditure  of  $1  million  on  education 
may  yield  social  benefits  that  are  valued  far  in  excess  of  this  amount.^  The  second 
point  is  that  a  tax  burden  of  a  specified  dollar  amount  will  involve  significantly 
different  real  burdens,  depending  on  whom  it  falls  upon — i.e.,  according  to  its 
particular  distribution  both  as  among  income  groups  and  within  each  income 
group.  These  differential  effects  likewise  relate  to  the  real  benefits  from  govern- 
ment expenditure. 

4.  In  theory,  the  incidence  of  money  burdens  and  benefits  arising  from 
government  taxation  and  expenditure  programs  could  be  determined  by  comparing 
the  present  distribution  of  income  with  the  hypothetical  distribution  that  would 
prevail  in  the  absence  of  taxes  and  governmental  services.  Unfortunately,  this 
second  distribution  cannot  be  determined  because  tax  and  expenditure  programs 
change  the  supplies  and  demands  both  of  factors  of  production  and  of  goods  and 
services.  As  a  consequence,  the  level  and  distribution  of  national  income  may  be 
significantly  different  from  what  they  would  be  in  the  hypothetical  situation  from 
which  government  is  absent.  The  most  that  can  therefore  be  done  in  this  kind  of 
study  is  to  relate  the  actual  dollar  amounts  of  taxes  paid  by  each  income  class  and 
the  actual  dollar  amount  of  expenditures  deemed  to  benefit  the  members  of  that 


"Recent  empirical  work  would  seem  to  indicate  that  property  values  tend  to  rise 
when  local  improvements  are  undertaken.  This  suggests  that  the  benefits  to  be  derived 
from  improvements  are  valued  more  highly  than  the  taxes  necessary  to  pay  for  them, 
the  difference  in  the  valuation  being  capitalized  and  reflected  in  higher  property  values. 

142 


Chapter  5 :  Paragraphs  2-7 

class.  Because  these  amounts  will  typically  not  be  equal,  the  revenue  and  expendi- 
ture programs  of  government  occasion  a  redistribution  of  income  as  among  income 
classes.  The  main  purpose  of  this  study  is  to  estimate  the  extent  of  this  redistribu- 
tion, recognizing  that  even  rough  approximations  will  appreciably  advance  our 
present  knowledge  in  this  crucial  aspect  of  government  finance. 

5.  As  already  explained,  we  shall  appraise  the  tax  and  expenditure  programs 
that  impinge  upon  Ontario  residents  solely  in  terms  of  their  impact  upon  the  income 
distribution  of  these  residents.  We  recognize  that  the  dimensions  of  economic 
welfare  embrace  much  more  than  income  and  include  such  additional  factors  as 
asset  holdings,  asset  liquidity,  regularity  of  income  receipt,  and  access  to  lending 
facilities.  The  distributional  implications  of  tax  and  expenditure  programs  could 
undoubtedly  be  investigated  with  respect  to  one  or  other  of  these  dimensions  of 
welfare,  but  we  think  that  the  use  of  income  as  our  criterion  is  readily  defended. 
In  the  first  place,  income  is  now  widely  regarded  as  the  best  single  index  of  rela- 
tive economic  welfare.  Second,  and  more  important,  it  may  be  argued  that  all 
taxes  are  ultimately  paid  out  of  the  incomes  of  individuals,  whatever  the  initial 
assessment  formula.  Finally,  the  use  of  this  base  is  in  accordance  with  the  practice 
of  comparable  studies  that  have  been  conducted  in  other  countries.  For  these 
reasons,  the  impact  of  government  on  the  distribution  of  income  has  been  the 
primary  subject  of  this  investigation. 

6.  The  taxpaying  unit  that  we  utilize  is  the  "economic  family",  defined  as  "a 
group  of  two  or  more  persons  living  together  and  related  to  each  other  by  blood, 
marriage,  or  adoption".^  To  this  type  of  unit  must  be  added  non-famUy  individuals 
who  reside  either  by  themselves  or  with  an  unrelated  household.  The  use  of  the 
economic-family  concept  may  be  justified  on  two  distinct  grounds.  First,  such  a 
family  typically  pools  its  resources  and  behaves  economically  as  a  single  unit. 
Similarly,  the  unattached  individual  is  an  economically  separate  decision-making 
unit.  Second,  the  use  of  these  units  finds  practical  justification  in  the  fact  that 
much  of  the  available  relevant  data  are  classified  with  respect  to  them.  The  pro- 
cedure adopted  in  the  study  is  therefore  to  classify  Ontario  residents  first  as 
families  and  unattached  individuals  and  then  to  classify  these  categories  with  respect 
to  size  of  income. 

7.  The  particular  income  concept  that  we  utilize  in  classifying  families  and 
unattached  individuals  is  money  income,  the  major  components  of  which  are  wages 
and  salaries,  farm  income,  investment  income,  income  from  self-employment,  and 
transfer  payments.  This  concept  conforms  rather  closely  to  what  most  families 
generally  regard  as  their  "income".  Moreover,  many  of  the  basic  data  series  used  in 
the  study  are  classified  with  respect  to  this  interpretation.  In  some  respects, 
however,  it  is  not  a  totally  satisfactory  measure.  It  ignores  the  imputed  rental 
value  of  owner-occupied  housing,  food  and  fuel  produced  and  consumed  on  the 
farm,  and  other  income  components  that  undoubtedly  contribute  to  taxable  capacity. 
It  also  fails  to  treat  tax  burdens  and  governmental  benefits  in   a  symmetrical 


^Dominion  Bureau  of  Statistics,  Census  Division,  Characteristics  of  Economic  Families, 
Ottawa:  Queen's  Printer,  1959. 

143 


Incidence  of  Government  Revenue  and  Expenditure 

fashion,  which  would  necessitate  viewing  the  former  as  a  subtraction  from,  and  the 
latter  as  an  addition  to,  income.  In  consequence,  although  we  have  determined 
the  basic  income  distribution  used  in  the  study  with  reference  to  money  income, 
when  we  turn  to  the  estimating  of  effective  rates  of  taxation  and  of  benefits,  we 
introduce  a  somewhat  more  comprehensive  measure  of  income. 

8.  In  the  following  sections  of  this  chapter,  we  first  consider  the  methods  of 
estimating  tax  and  expenditure  incidence.  We  then  determine  the  net  burdens  and 
benefits  relating  to  each  money-income  class,  and  use  the  results  to  develop  the 
concept  of  Adjusted  Broad  Income,  this  being  more  comprehensive  than  that  of 
money  income.  For  each  income  class,  the  rates  of  net  burden  and  benefit  are 
then  determined  by  dividing  their  dollar  amounts  by  the  amounts  of  adjusted 
income  in  each  money-income  class.  Finally,  we  analyse  the  distributional  impact 
of  government  finance  by  reference  to  the  resulting  effective  burden  and  benefit 
rates. 

THE  BASIS  OF  ESTIMATING  INCIDENCE 

9.  The  following  paragraphs  provide  no  more  than  a  summary  statement  of 
the  techniques  that  we  have  used  in  allocating  tax  revenues  to  the  various  income 
groups  within  this  province.  The  reader  who  wishes  to  ascertain  precisely  how  our 
results  were  obtained  is  referred  to  the  monograph  on  which  this  chapter  is  based.* 
Here  we  simply  outline  our  general  procedure  and  list  our  major  assumptions 
relating  to  the  shifting  and  incidence  of  taxation. 

10.  The  funds  allocated  by  income  group  encompass  virtually  all  sources  of 
governmental  revenue.  In  addition  to  tax  revenues,  they  include  revenues  from 
licences  and  fees,  fines  and  penalties,  and  profits  from  the  sale  of  alcoholic 
beverages.  This  inclusive  coverage  is  dictated  by  our  desire  to  treat  revenues  as 
comprehensively  as  expenditures — all  of  which  are  included  in  our  study — and  by 
the  difficulty  of  justifying  any  particular  dividing  line  between  those  revenues  that 
might  be  included  and  those  excluded. 

1 1 .  The  allocation  of  taxes  to  particular  income  groups  involves  the  formula- 
tion of  reasonable  assumptions  regarding  their  shifting  and  incidence.  Is  the 
burden  of  a  particular  tax  likely  to  rest  with  the  legal  taxpayer  or  will  it  in  some 
degree  be  shifted  forward  to  purchasers  of  the  legal  taxpayer's  products  or  services, 
or  back  to  those  from  whom  the  legal  taxpayer  makes  purchases?  Such  shifting 
as  in  fact  occurs  is  determined  both  by  the  type  of  tax  levied  and  by  the  position 
of  the  taxpayer  in  the  market-place.  We  observe  that  the  "openness"  of  the  Ontario 
economy  considerably  complicates  our  analysis,  in  that  traditional  incidence  theory 
has  been  concerned  mainly  with  the  problem  of  identifying  tax  burdens  in  the 
context  of  a  self-contained  economy.  The  complications  of  determining  incidence 
in  a  jurisdiction  having  extensive  external  economic  transactions  are  substantial. 

12.  Having    formulated    the    most    appropriate    assumptions    concerning    tax 
incidence,  it  then  becomes  possible  to  allocate  the  various  tax  burdens  to  the 

*See  Johnson,  Incidence  of  Government  Revenues  and  Expenditures. 

144 


Chapter  5:  Paragraphs  8-13 

appropriate  economic  groups.  A  consideration  of  the  extent  to  which  these  economic 
groups  are  resident  in  Ontario  then  permits  a  division  of  the  tax  burdens  between 
provincial  residents  and  non-residents.  Finally,  when  it  has  been  decided  how 
much  of  each  tax  or  other  revenue  source  should  be  imputed  to  each  of  the  resident 
economic  groups,  this  amount  must  be  converted  into  a  distribution  of  burdens 
among  the  various  income  classes.  Thus,  if  it  has  been  determined  that  a  particular 
levy  burdens  the  consumers  of  a  specific  class  of  commodities,  consumption  studies 
may  indicate  the  division,  by  income  classes,  of  total  expenditure  on  this  class  of 
commodities.  The  total  levy  may  then  be  allocated  among  the  income  classes  in 
proportion  to  total  expenditure  on  the  commodities  in  question. 

- 13.  We  have  already  observed  that  some  part  of  the  burden  of  taxation  initially 
imposed  upon  Ontario  taxpayers  is  shifted  to  non-residents.  This  process  is  effected 
either  through  purchases  that  non-residents  make  within  Ontario — as  for  example 


Table  5 : 1 

GOVERNMENTAL  REVENUES  BY  SOURCE,  1961 

(millions  of  dollars) 

Other 
Ontario  Provincial  Provincial  and 

and  Municipal  Federal  Municipal       ^ 

. Total 

Ontario  Ontario       Ontario       Ontario 

Revenue  Item  Total        Share*  Total         Share*        Share*      Payments 

Personalincome  tax 120.7  120.7        1,850.0  847.4  —  968.1 

Corporation  income  tax 151.8t  56.2        1,232.0  373.3  56.9  486.4 

General  sales  tax 141.2t         127.9        1,045.0  352.0  —  479.9 

Highway-user  revenues 247.1  146.8  —  —  48.6  195.4 

Selective  excise  taxes 94.7§  83.0  623.0**       181.4  —  264.4 

Succession  duties 40.4  39.0  71.0  34.5  —  73.5 

Import  duties —  —  535.0  180.1  —  180.1 

Property  tax 644.8tt  456.1  —  —  90.1  546.2 

Natural-resource  revenue 43.1             17.0  —  —  65.6  82.6 

Social  insurance  contributions .         89.0            72.0  394.0  163.0  —  235.0 

Other  taxes  and  miscellaneous 
revenue 186.5||       164.7  107.8  38.1  21.1  223.9 

Total 1,759.3        1,283.4        5,857.8        2,169.8  282.3        3,735.5 

Sources:  Dominion  Bureau  of  Statistics,  Financial  Statistics  of  the  Government  of 
Canada,  1961;  Financial  Statistics  of  Provincial  Governments,  1961:  Financial 
Statistics  of  Municipal  Governments,  1961.  Municipal  data  refer  to  calendar 
years,  federal  and  provincial  data  to  nearest  fiscal  years. 

*The  amount  paid  by  non-residents  of  Ontario  is  estimated  utilizing  the  assumptions 
made  regarding  the  shifting  of  taxes  to  non-residents. 

flncludes  small  amount  of  tax,  collected  under  The  Corporations  Tax  Act,  that  is  not 
based  on  income. 

JThe  figure  shown  represents  an  estimate  of  the  yield  of  this  tax  for  12  months.  Since 
it  was  actually  in  effect  for  only  7  months  of  the  year,  the  annual  revenue  is  obtained 
by  multiplying  the  actual  yield  by  12/7. 

§Includes  amusement  taxes  and  revenue  from  liquor  sales  and  licences. 
**Includes  excises  on  liquor,  tobacco,  automobiles,  and  other  commodities, 
t flncludes  the  business  levy  as  well  as  the  property  tax. 

ttThe  largest  item  is  hospital  premiums  ($89.5  million).     Includes  licences  (other  than 
liquor  and  motor  vehicle),  fines,  tax  on  premium  income  of  insurance  companies. 

145 


Incidence  of  Government  Revenue  and  Expenditure 


u 
</) 

< 

U 

s 
o 
u 

z 

>< 

u 

z 
o 

d    Is 

<;    T3 
o 

^     c 

w    s 

n 

< 

H 

O 

o 
p 

D 
n 

H 


2"^ 


2  s:  s 


1-M 


s  5 


^? 


■AS 

O  bo 


g 

8 

8 

8 

8 

g 

g 

g 

8 

8 

8 

8 

8 

8 

8 

r- 

00 

<N 

r~ 

^ 

«-^ 

^ 

m 

r~- 

fM 

<r> 

m 

m 

o 

1-H 

I—I 

r- 

■* 

O 

m 

OS 

OS 

5 

<s" 

3 

o' 

ri 

r- 

fS 

ir> 

Tl- 

■<t 

OS 

Tl- 

■<«■ 

00 

OO 

SO 

oo 

w-i 

OS 

" 

fS 

O^ 

<r\ 

SO 

1 

m 

s 

^ 

f? 

f'l 

/-^ 

2 

1 

r^ 

G" 

<r> 

•^ 

00 

00 

1 

vo 

^ 

VO 

1 

<N 

<N 

<N 

so 

<N 

^-^ 

"•^^ 

N.^ 

*^^ 

g 

8 

o 
o 

8 

8 

g 

g 

8 

g 

8 

8 

8 

8 

so 

r<^ 

r*l 

r-^ 

Tt 

*-H 

^ 

<N 

SO 

yr\ 

<s 

so 

p^ 

1 

>r> 

m 

8 

1-^ 

«-H 

SO 

r^ 

1 

Cvf 

r~ 

OS 

oC 

OS* 

oo 

o\ 

r-^ 

T-H 

cs 

^H 

1 

i-^ 

r- 

m 

•* 

OS 

fS 

'"' 

8 

8 

8 

8 

00^ 

1 

1 

1 

1 

8 
>n 

>n 

8 

so 

1 

8 

8 

oo 

q 

\o 

r-' 

VO 

p^ 

OS 

r-- 

<N 

Os" 

fS 

-*' 

>ri 

1-^ 

rf 

00 

rs 

<ri 

<N 

•<a- 

00 

m 

^1^ 

r- 

oo 

f<l 

00 

JN 

r«-i 

•^ 

OS 

r- 

•^ 

■* 

<s 

3 

00 

so 

o 

SO 

OS 

<S 

oo 

■* 

<S 

00 

■«1- 

r~ 

r~ 

o 

m 

Q 

■* 

<o 

o 

Tl- 

OS 

OS 

r- 

so 

PO 

o 

<ri 

rf 

<s 

CN 

Q 

r- 

r-- 

oo 

o 

oo 

O 

■* 

r~ 

pn 

■* 

On 

r-' 

o 

o" 

OS 

<r> 

Os 

w-T 

so* 

r-* 

3 

t-~' 

so 

oo 

fO 

«N 

ro 

so 

r- 

_ 

<0 

t^ 

o\ 

OS 

^ 

00 

r- 

r- 

00 

Os 

r- 

3 

r5 

<0 

00 

OS 

r~ 

m 

SO 

Tt 

00 

SO 

c^ 

o 

■* 

^. 

fl 

Os^ 

<N 

^ 

Os^ 

<N 

r-_^ 

•<t 

1-^ 

r- 

<s 

ro 

oC 

«-^ 

oo 

,.1^ 

ro 

00 

Tt 

so 

r-" 

o* 

SO 

r- 

Tf 

m 

m 

m 

n 

r- 

00 

OS 

•* 

5 

m 

m 

«N 

3 

so 

Tt 

fO 

m 

w-> 

m 

m 

3 

r- 

«N 

*r\ 

00 

00 

■* 

o 

r- 

s 

5 

00 

<N 

00 

■<* 

^f 

OS 

00 

«N 

m 

<n 

<n 

00 

OS 

<r> 

^^ 

vo' 

"X" 

•rT 

po 

rf 

rf 

OO 

r}-' 

o 

t- 

O 

00 

m 

o 

•* 

<s 

<s 

fN 

r^ 

<s 

o\ 

r- 

r- 

VO 

o 

00 

00 

r4 

m 

<S 

lO 

p^ 

1 

o\ 

r- 

00 

<N 

o 

>o 

00 

m 

m 

fS 

TT 

o 

Os 

m 

CT\ 

'*- 

<S 

r-_^ 

^ 

sO__ 

Tt 

<s 

Tt 

ON 

<S^ 

Os_^ 

«-H 

f<^ 

o' 

</^ 

00 

ro' 

cs" 

r-^ 

o' 

■* 

Tt 

^N 

1-^ 

pn 

SO 

^^ 

<S 

o 

SO 

r- 

<ri 

ON 

■«1- 

VO 

ir> 

OS 

so 

so 

o 

s 

r~ 

pp> 

<S 

OJ 

o 

vO 

yr\ 

r- 

OS 

IT) 

ir> 

r<> 

>o 

«n 

m 

so 

r~ 

O 

o. 

m 

<N 

in 

t~ 

Os^ 

00 

t-^ 

<o 

o 

r- 

■* 

■"t 

rf 

o' 

r~-' 

'"' 

"o 

Os' 

ri 

r-* 
■n 

^* 

ri 

■*" 

SO* 

VO 

o 

5 

OS 

5 

ir> 

n- 

m 

<n 

so 

00 

>r> 

00 

r~ 

5 

so 

o 

<s 

rN 

o 

r- 

o 

Os 

q_ 

o^ 

oo 

\Q 

00 

^ 

m 

■<t 

00 

r- 

<N 

r- 

ro 

VO" 

>o 

<s 

m 

00 

n 

r^ 
m 

gi 

f^ 

pn 

s 

<s 

§ 

■"I- 

o 

00 

g 

O 

8 

S 

so 

r~ 

c^ 

OS 

<n 

Wl 

^ 

<s 

r^ 

r~ 

OS 

ppi 

rf 

<o 

r^ 

m 

— 

CN 

PO 

00 

ro 

5 

.«  8 


•S         2     2 


2    .2     V 


|i 
11 

5  c 

c  o 
o  — 


.1^ 


O       1- 

c 

O       I* 

U    O 


X    UJ    c/]    Z    o) 


o 


(«       — ; 


o 


>  X 

Pi  - 

St 

C   u 


3 

O 

<U 

c 

(4 

, , 

5 

u 

c 

<« 

H 

146 


Chapter  5:  Table  5:2 


.S   3 

>  c 
o  « 

t-,  > 

a,  u 
.2_! 

51 
si 

H 


m  00  vo 

■*  O  vo 

w  Tt  r~_^ 

rn  ^  0\ 


t~-     c->     r<t 

m      O      -^ 
-H      m     en 


«N    <N    <N    00    --a- 

vo     >n     r4     vo      <N 


—1      m 


c 

o 

S    KJ    " 

C    4>    o 


Sn 


C  (U  o 
^  C  rt 


-H      —<      m 


^        -^        <N        -H 


m 

■<t 

O 

o\ 

>o 

O 

00 

1-H 

r~^ 

o' 

V£> 

-H 

<N       -H      <S 


00       «N       «N       00 


00     <s     <n 


<N      OO      VO 


ro      <N      v^ 


<0      On      >0      >0      Tj- 

</^      00      00      On      ^ 


o-=    - 


3     2 


.C       U      3       iu 

•SP    o     tS    £ 

S    eu    Z    O 


|_i         CO        •"  C3 


O  <N  "o  m 
w->  m  •^  «N 
00     n  - 


s 


8   8 


Tt         lO         t~ 

0\     m     O 
m     >o     •— I 


ts 

oo 

m 

_ 

VO 

^H 

rf 

On 

o 

Wl 

a\ 

■t 

m 

cn 

<r» 

v£) 

<D 

00 

vo 

Tl- 

<N 

m 

8 

8 

g 

8 

g 

g 

8 

8 

rf 

m 

O 

■* 

<n 

^ 

r-' 

fn 

<N 

1-H 

■^ 

m 

o 

00 

■* 

»^ 

«r> 

OO 

m 

VO 

oo 

m 

oo 

m 

m 

^^ 

'— < 

^H 

>0      m      so      rn 
ON      fN      <N      r~- 


m     m     Tj-     -H 


m     m     ON     f*^ 


m     VO     00     r«^ 


— ,      — I      ■* 


■* 

>o 

2; 

OO 

m 

.—I 

<rl 

ON 

<N 

m     <o     *s 


00       >0      On 


B  e 

3  o  ■;! 

C  CJ  c 

u  c  o 

11  ^ 

S  o     - 

TOM  lT         C 

Pu 


<N  CM  «^ 

-H  ir>  On 

NO  tS  r<^ 

O  -H  00 


NO  m  <S 

00  CM  — 

<N  <n  no_^ 

o'  o'  "^ 


r4     ON     '— 


On      <N      00 


5 


w     2 

Ja     B 

o   w 


£    S 


•-    t:    =-       «» 


8 


5 


u 


u 


2  S 

c  C 
>  <u 

4>    > 

a!  o 

?^ 

i3 
o 

H 


147 


Incidence  of  Government  Revenue  and  Expenditure 

in  tourists'  purchases — or  through  the  higher  prices,  reflecting  the  forward  shifting 
of  taxes,  that  must  be  paid  for  the  exports  of  the  province.  The  extent  to  which 
tax  burdens  may  be  shifted  to  non-residents  will  depend  upon  the  competitive 
position  of  Ontario  producers  in  outside  markets,  these  encompassing  markets 
in  other  provinces  as  well  as  in  other  nations.  Where  producers  are  able  to  exercise 
significant  control  over  prices,  shifting  possibilities  will  exist  in  external  markets  in 
the  same  way  as  in  markets  within  this  province.  On  the  other  hand,  if  trade  must 
be  carried  on  at  established  world  prices,  there  will  be  little  room  for  shifting  tax 
burdens  to  non-residents. 

14.  Given  the  present  diversity  of  markets  and  market  structures  in  which 
Ontario  production  is  sold,  it  is  extremely  difficult  to  determine  the  extent  to  which 
those  tax  burdens,  reflected  in  higher  prices,  are  in  fact  exported  to  non-residents. 
A  thorough  analysis  would  require  an  examination  of  the  internal  and  external 
market  conditions  for  each  class  of  commodities,  a  task  far  beyond  the  compass  of 
this  study.  In  consequence,  we  have  found  it  necessary  to  make  several  rather 
arbitrary  assumptions.  The  first  relates  to  federal  taxation,  and  indicates  that 
18  per  cent  of  that  part  of  the  burden  reflected  in  higher  prices  is  exported  to 
non-residents  of  Canada.  This  selected  percentage  reflects  the  ratio  of  the  dollar 
value  of  exported  goods  to  Gross  Domestic  Product.  The  remainder  of  the  shifted 
federal  tax  burden  is  then  allocated  as  among  Ontario  and  the  other  provinces  in 
proportion  to  the  aggregate  consumption  expenditure  of  their  residents.  Similar 
computations  were  then  made  concerning  the  proportions  of  the  various  provincial 
and  municipal  burdens  shifted  forward  through  higher  prices,  and  for  each  of 
these  levels  of  government  comparable  assumptions  were  formulated  concerning 
the  distribution  of  the  shifted  burden  as  between  residents  and  non-residents  of  the 
province.  In  summary,  the  percentage  shares  of  the  total  Canadian  burden  of  these 
forward-shifted  taxes  which  are  assumed  to  be  borne  by  Ontario  residents  are  as 
follows : 

(1)  Federal  taxes ,     .     .     .     .     37% 

(2)  Ontario  provincial  and  municipal  taxes   ....     50% 

( 3 )  Other  provincial  and  municipal  taxes      .     .     .     .     3 1  % 

15.  Another  possible  mechanism  by  means  of  which  tax  burdens  may  be  trans- 
ferred to  non-residents  is  through  tax-reduced  rates  of  return  on  capital  invested  in 
the  taxing  jurisdiction.  The  unshifted  portions  of  the  corporate  income  tax  and  of 
property  taxes  both  reduce  the  net  rate  of  return  to  capital,  and  thereby  cause 
some  part  of  their  burden  to  be  transferred  to  non-residents,  the  actual  transfer 
being  roughly  proportional  to  the  ratio  of  non-resident  to  resident  capital  holdings 
subject  to  taxation.  Because  foreign  investment  accounted  for  approximately  34 
per  cent  of  total  investment  in  Canada  in  1961,  we  assigned  to  Canadian  residents 
66  per  cent  of  the  burdens  on  profits.  The  Ontario  share  of  this  burden  was  deter- 
mined as  the  proportion  of  dividends  received  by  Canadians  that  accrued  to  resi- 
dents of  this  province. 

16.  By  methods  similar  to  those  used  to  estimate  the  extent  to  which  taxes 
imposed  in  Ontario  were  exported  to  non-residents,  the  burdens  imported  into 

148 


Chapter  5:  Paragraphs  14-21 

Ontario  from  other  jurisdictions  were  also  estimated.  Table  5:1,  which  summarizes 
these  results,  shows,  for  the  federal  government,  the  Ontario  government  and 
municipal  governments  within  Ontario,  the  total  receipts  from  each  revenue  source 
and  the  share  of  these  receipts  borne  by  Ontario  residents.  Also  shown  are  the 
burdens  of  taxes  of  other  jurisdictions  borne  by  Ontario  residents. 

17.  When  revenue  burdens  have  been  assigned  to  the  various  economic  groups 
and  categories  in  accordance  with  our  assumptions  regarding  shifting  and  incidence, 
we  then  distribute  these  burdens  among  the  family  money-income  classes.  The 
results  obtained  by  this  procedure  are  summarized  in  Table  5:2,  where  the  dollar 
amounts  assigned  to  each  family  money-income  class  are  shown. 

THE  METHOD  OF  ESTIMATING  THE  INCIDENCE  OF  GOVERNMENT 
EXPENDITURES 

18.  Any  analysis  of  the  impact  of  government  finance  on  income  distribution 
would  be  incomplete  without  a  consideration  of  the  manner  in  which  the  benefits 
derived  from  governmental  expenditures  accrue  to  different  income  classes. 
Unfortunately,  this  subject  has  received  less  attention  in  the  literature  of  public 
finance  than  has  the  comparable  problem  of  tax  incidence,  which  suggests  that  the 
results  obtained  here  should  be  considered  more  tentative  than  those  in  our 
preceding  section. 

19.  In  analysing  the  incidence  of  governmental  expenditures,  it  is  useful  to 
distinguish  between  transfer  payments  (for  example,  old  age  security  and  family 
allowance  payments)  and  expenditures  on  goods  and  services.  We  treat  the  former 
as  negative  taxes  which  are  assumed  to  augment  the  income  of  the  recipients  by 
the  amount  of  the  transfers  received.  Expenditures  on  goods  and  services  are  more 
difficult  to  deal  with.  Ideally,  it  is  desirable  to  consider  the  distribution  of  welfare 
gains  generated  by  the  expenditure  programs.  In  practice,  however,  we  have  noted 
that  this  is  impossible.  Public  expenditure  programs  that  satisfy  social  wants 
usually  do  not  involve  direct  sales  to  consumers  and  there  is  therefore  no  market 
price  that  can  be  used  as  a  money  measure  of  the  welfare  gained  by  the  consumer. 
Lacking  such  an  indicator,  we  have  found  it  necessary  to  adopt  the  alternative 
approach  of  determining  the  distribution,  by  income  class,  of  costs  incurred  on 
behalf  of  families  and  unattached  individuals.  These  costs  are  viewed  as  com- 
ponents of  the  real  incomes  of  the  beneficiaries — components  that  should  be  added 
to  their  money  incomes  in  arriving  at  a  more  comprehensive  income  concept. 

20.  In  allocating  to  various  income  classes  the  costs  incurred  on  behalf  of 
their  members,  we  take  account  only  of  the  direct  beneficiaries.  While  we  recognize 
that  educational  expenditures,  for  example,  yield  benefits  to  virtually  all  citizens, 
the  procedure  that  we  have  adopted  allocates  the  total  expenditure  upon  education 
among  families  in  proportion  to  student  members.  This  approach  is  dictated  by  the 
lack  of  available  data  on  the  distribution  of  indirect  benefits  by  income  class. 

21.  The  technique  used  to  estimate  the  distributional  impact  of  government 
expenditures  is  similar  to  that  used  in  the  determination  of  tax  incidence.  Having 
classified  the  expenditure  items  to  be  included  in  our  analysis,  we  then  formulated 

149 


Incidence  of  Government  Revenue  and  Expenditure 

assumptions  concerning  the  likelihood  of  the  shifting  of  benefits,  and  these  results 
were  used  to  determine  the  beneficiaries  on  whose  behalf  the  expenditures  were 
made.^  A  consideration  of  the  composition  of  the  beneficiary  groups  then  permitted 
the  non-resident  share  of  each  type  of  expenditure  to  be  deducted  from  the  total. 
Finally,  the  remaining  benefits  accruing  to  residents  were  allocated  to  the  various 
income  classes  by  reference  to  the  distribution  of  the  beneficiary  groups  among  the 
income  classes. 

22.  In  addition  to  distinguishing  between  transfer  payments  and  governmental 
expenditures  on  goods  and  services,  we  also  found  it  necessary  to  differentiate 
between  specific  and  general  governmental  expenditures.  The  former  category 
includes  those  expenditure  items  whose  beneficiaries  are  readily  identifiable. 
Approximately  70  per  cent  of  total  expenditures  fall  into  the  specific  category.  The 
remaining  30  per  cent  comprises  expenditure  items,  such  as  those  on  national 
defence,  general  government  and  protection,  that  benefit  the  entire  population  but 
whose  benefit  pattern  is  ill-defined.  While  there  is  no  generally  accepted  best 
method  by  which  these  expenditures  may  be  allocated  to  different  income  classes, 
such  an  allocation  must  be  made  if  the  net  distributional  impact  of  government  is 
to  be  determined.  To  omit  these  items  while  including  revenue  sources  in  their 
entirety  would  understate  the  net  benefits  of  government  and  misrepresent  the  dis- 
tributive impact  of  its  fiscal  operations. 

23.  In  the  literature  of  public  finance,  a  number  of  alternative  assumptions 
have  been  developed  as  the  basis  for  allocating  the  benefits  of  general  expenditures. 
Thus,  it  has  been  assumed  in  some  studies  that  all  individuals  benefit  equally  from 
such  expenditures.  In  others,  the  assumption  that  families  rather  than  individuals 
benefit  equally  has  been  preferred.  A  third  assumption  occasionally  encountered 
is  that  families  benefit  from  general  expenditures  in  proportion  to  their  total  income. 
Lastly,  some  studies  have  assumed  that  families  benefit  from  such  expenditures  in 
a  manner  proportional  to  their  investment  income. 

24.  While  for  some  types  of  general  expenditures  some  one  of  these  hypo- 
theses may  be  preferable  to  the  others,  we  think  that  there  are  no  clear  grounds  for 
any  over-all  priority.  We  therefore  have  made  no  attempt  in  this  study  to  vary  our 
assumptions  with  the  type  of  general  outlay.  We  have  chosen  to  apply  each  of  the 
four  hypotheses  to  the  entire  range  of  general  expenditure  and  the  distribution  that 
we  employ  reflects  the  average  of  the  results  obtained  by  using  each  assumption 
in  turn. 

25.  The  reader  should  note  particularly  that  unconditional  grants  from  one 
level  of  government  to  another  are  omitted  from  the  expenditures  of  the  paying 
level  of  government,  and  from  the  income  of  the  recipient  level.  This  practice  is 
dictated  by  the  desire  to  avoid  double  counting  and  an  overstatement  of  the  total 
burden  of  government.  Conditional  grants,  on  the  other  hand,  are  shown  as 
expenditures  of  the  paying  government. 

'Some  of  the  more  important  of  the  assumptions  regarding  shifting  are  listed  in  the 
appendix  to  this  chapter. 

150 


Chapter  5:  Paragraphs  22-27 

Table  5:3 

ALLOCATION  OF  GOVERNMENTAL  EXPENDITURES,  1961 

(millions  of  dollars) 

Ontario  Other 

~  Provincial  and 

Provincial  Municipal  Federal Municipal       Total 

Ontario  Ontario  Ontario       Ontario       Ontario 

Expenditure  item         Total      Share*      Total      Share*  Total      Share*        Share*       Receipts 

Highways,  roads  and 

bridges 246.2      174.0       134.2         96.5  89.0         34.9  39.8  345.2 

Other  transportation 

and  communicationt  —  —  —            —  305.0  80.4  —  80.4 

Education 271.0  271.0  343.6  343.6  93.0  36.0  —  650.6 

Health  and  sanitation .  228.4  228.4  139.1  114.6  366.0  125.3             6.5  474.8 

Interest 49.4  17.6  40.2         12.9  653.4  240.8  19.5  290.8 

Social  welfare t 116.8  116.8  27.3  27.3  2,266.0  772.2  —  916.3 

Agriculture 9.5  9.5  —            —  295.0  118.1  —  127.6 

General  expenditure§.  142.5  118.6  274.4  229.5  2,678.4  945.7  55.9  1,349.7 

Total 1,063.8      935.9       958.8       824.4      6,745.8    2,353.4  121.7         4,235.4 

Sources:  Dominion  Bureau  of  Statistics,  Financial  Statistics  of  the  Government  of 
Canada,  1961;  Financial  Statistics  of  Provincial  Governments,  1961;  Financial 
Statistics  of  Municipal  Governments,  1961.  Municipal  data  refer  to  calendar 
years,  federal  and  provincial  data  to  nearest  fiscal  years. 

*The  amounts  of  the  various  expenditures  received  by  non-residents  are  estimated  with 
the  aid  of  the  assumptions  regarding  the  incidence  of  each  type  of  expenditure. 

tincludes  expenditure  on  air,  water  and  rail  transport. 

^Includes  old  age  security  payments,  family  allowances,  government  pensions,  payments 
to  veterans,  unemployment  insurance  and  other  miscellaneous  transfer  payments. 

§The  major  components  in  this  general  category  are  defence  services  and  mutual  aid, 
general  government,  protection  of  persons  and  property,  recreation  and  cultural 
services,  natural  resources  and  primary  industries  and  payments  to  government 
enterprises. 

26.  As  indicated  above,  some  of  the  benefits  of  governmental  expenditures 
accrue  to  non-residents.  Foreign  ownership  of  businesses  located  in  Canada  is  the 
primary  vehicle  by  means  of  which  this  exportation  occurs.  The  various  expendi- 
ture items  allocated  in  the  study  are  presented  in  summary  form  in  Table  5:3, 
while  their  distribution  among  family  income  classes  is  shown  in  Table  5:4. 


BURDENS  AND  BENEFITS,  BY  MONEY-INCOME  CLASSES 

27.  Our  analysis  has  now  been  developed  to  the  point  where  it  is  possible  to 
present,  in  Tables  5 : 2  and  5 : 4,  the  aggregate  monetary  burden  imposed  upon  each 
family  money-income  class  of  Ontario  residents  and  the  aggregate  money  benefits 
accruing  from  expenditures  on  their  behalf.  We  emphasize  that  this  distribution 
encompasses  the  fiscal  operations  of  all  levels  of  government  within  Canada. 
Because  the  number  of  economic  units — i.e.,  families  and  unattached  individuals — 
varies  among  money-income  classes,  the  data  in  Tables  5:2  and  5:4  do  not  directly 
indicate  the  manner  in  which  tax  burdens  and  expenditure  benefits  vary  in  relation 
to  money  income.  For  this  purpose,  the  dollar  amounts  of  burden  and  benefit  must 
be  converted  to  effective  rates,  an  objective  easily  achieved  by  dividing  the  dollar 

151 


Incidence  of  Government  Revenue  and  Expenditure 


(/3 

u 

< 

U 
M 

8 

z 

I 

>^ 

ULl 

i 


s"^ 


*.   1    s: 
c  s:  ^ 


O   Ci 

SI 

ii 

t\Os 

8 


o 

Si 

u   C 

-—  {/I 

C    CQ 
W   O 


.2  J 

.E  00 

oX 


I       I     ^      I 


8   8   8   8 

vO      00      «->      VO 


m     o 


00      O 


<N      <S      — 


r<^        'O       00       f*^        00       00 


ON        -H        OS 

r^     «n     m 


r- 

On 

<N 

ro 

*^ 

r~ 

«N 

n 

<N 

vo 

ON 

00 

ON 

m 

f^     NO     m     -" 


>0       OO       NO 


ir>     rvl     NO 


6^ 

NO 

NO 
NO_^ 

oo' 

OOn 
6S 

On' 

NO 

o 

00_^ 
no' 

3 

ON 

no' 

r4 

m 

On' 

NO  lO  On 

.  .        _       ,  >0  ir>  NO 

ON     —     NO     tN)^  OO  m 

no"    (n     — <'    -J'    •^'  r-' 


ON  —  <N 

O  ON  — > 

O^  <N  rn 

fN  — '  — ' 


NO         -^ 

On'      r-n' 


1/^  vO  ON  \0 
ON  <0  r~-_  On 
— '      — '      m'      r^ 


a       O 


X     ^ 


8 


^    I   ^ 


cd     y     (u 


<    O 


8 


8   8 


-^      m      —H 


8 


NO       NO       On       r'l       </^ 

r»^     Tt     ri    t--'    oT 

Tl-       — I       -^      fS       fN 


tS      NO      m      O      — 

r»^      -^     oo      rn      '— 1 


</->       <N       </^ 


>0       00        NO       -H 

O     —     r-~     ON 
>ri     JN     00     (S 


00      On       «N 


<N       m      NO 


">  Si, 
^-  c 

a£ 

no. 


Tt      o 
rj-'      — ' 


O       rt 


s 


o 

00 

00 

r^ 

o 

(N 

m 

^^ 

<N 

■<a- 

NO     m     -^     On     rn     «-) 

00       00       NO  ~        ^ 


8 


m     <n     00 


r~     ^H     f«^     (^ 


<N       00       >/^      00       On 


m     NO     00     f^ 


5 


X  a  ^  6 


8 


8 


•o 
5a     X 

H 


^  c 
•aO 

—  !> 

.S-5 

>  c 
o  y 

Ou  X 

—  W 

o 
H 


152 


Chapter  5:  Table  5:4 


8   8   8   8 

oo     >/~i     V)     as 


-H  SO 


oo     m     <N     vo 


00      -^     m      <o 


<o      ON^     0\^ 


^     00     O     O 
<^     so     m     <s 


<N       SO 


m      m      <o      oo 


3 

'•5 

c 

X 


13 

c 

C3 


:^  00 


"5  c 

30 


so 


o  ti 
^  o 

I « 

00 


^  s  "      1- 


a 


c« 

!/> 

^^ 

U 

.5 

3 

'3 

c 

'•3 

■> 

c 

o 

u 

u 

a 

Ql, 

X 

_ 

u 

~      so 


8   8   8   8   8 


so^    00     a\_^ 

<N       r^     so'      <N 


r»^       ^H       CTs 

t—       OO       CT\ 

SO     <N     r- 


3t3 
.-  C3 
T3  O 
C  1- 
<U  , 
&  ^ 

k.   00 


t~     <N     00     rj     00 

>o     00     ts     —     r~ 

OS      OS      -^      <0      so 


3 


>0      ON       <N       (*! 


OS  00 
o  ■* 
t-     — 


r-    —    so 


0\      —      so      (N      <ri      <N 


On     OS     >ri 


OS      oo      <S 


fN      00      pi-> 


so 

00 

0\ 

?3 

S 

00 

rsT 

1^ 

O 
so' 

so' 

en 

00^ 

<o' 

fs     rs|     OS     -^     <s 


so     <s     so 

so      (N      ro 
OS      r<^      >ri 


00      tS      00      OS 


o 

Tt 

so 

^ 

«s' 

o' 

so' 

-* 

-^ 

o 

«     r-     — 


so    —    o 


"      w-i      —      «N 


--^      <S      00 


00      00      so 


C3      -^ 


^     ^    .2 


__       3 


a^       O 


O     W     K     £ 


•C      c 
00      w 


5 


-•      »     ^     -TS        ~ 


8 


2- 

3  C 
tJ  « 
■■?S 
C  C 

O.  <U 
X   S 

O 

H 


O 


153 


Incidence  of  Government  Revenue  and  Expenditure 

amounts  assigned  to  each  money-income  class  by  the  total  income  enjoyed  by  the 
members  of  that  class. 

28.  It  will  be  readily  apparent  that  the  resulting  effective  rates  for  the  several 
income  classes  and  the  pattern  of  variation  in  rates  from  class  to  class  will  depend 
upon  the  concept  of  income  that  is  chosen.  It  is  therefore  most  important  that  an 
appropriate  index  of  income  be  devised  and,  in  particular,  that  the  effects  of 
government  revenues  and  expenditures  upon  the  distribution  of  income  be  treated 
in  symmetrical  fashion.  This  will  be  achieved  where  the  income  base  is  defined  as 
including  all  fiscal  operations  of  the  public  sector  and  where,  as  a  result,  the 
distributive  effects  of  revenues  and  expenditures  will  be  expressed  as  percentages 
of  an  income  base  in  which  payments  to  government  have  been  subtracted  and 
benefits  from  government  added. 

ADJUSTED  BROAD  INCOME 

29.  In  Table  5:5,  we  present  an  income  distribution  that  satisfies  these 
requirements.  Family  money  income  has  been  adjusted  to  include  the  following 
elements  of  imputed  income:  the  rental  value  of  owner-occupied  homes,  interest 
income,  food  and  fuel  produced  and  consumed  on  farms,  and  the  investment 
income  of  life  insurance  companies.  In  addition,  the  retained  earnings  of  companies, 
together  with  the  unshifted  portion  of  the  corporate  income  tax  and  those  parts  of 
the  property  tax  and  government  natural  resource  revenue  that  are  borne  by  stock- 
holders, are  assigned  to  the  income  classes  in  proportion  to  dividends  received. 
These  last  adjustments  are  necessary  since,  where  unshifted  taxes  on  business  are 
allocated  to  the  owners  of  business,  consistency  requires  that  the  income  from  which 
the  taxes  are  paid  also  be  assigned  to  them.  From  the  resultant  income  distribution, 
payments  to  government  are  then  subtracted  and  benefits  received  are  added. 
Because  it  includes  the  governmental  sector,  and  to  distinguish  it  from  other 
income  concepts,  we  refer  to  what  emerges  from  these  adjustments  as  the  distribu- 
tion of  adjusted  broad  income.  The  desired  tax  and  benefit  rates  then  are  obtained 
by  dividing  the  dollar  amounts  of  payments  and  benefits  for  each  income  class, 
as  shown  in  Tables  5 : 2  and  5:4,  by  the  corresponding  amounts  of  adjusted  broad 
income  shown  in  Table  5:5.  Finally,  the  results  so  obtained  are  summarized  in 
Tables  5:6  and  5:7.® 

EFFECTIVE  RATES  OF  INCIDENCE 
EFFECTIVE  TAX  RATES 

30.  In  discussing  the  variation  in  effective  tax  and  benefit  rates  that  emerges 
from  our  study,  we  shall  use  the  terms  "progressive"  and  "regressive"  to  describe 
the  pattern.  Where  rate  variations  reflect  a  reduction  in  income  inequality,  the 
pattern  is  described  as  progressive.  Thus,  if  effective  tax  rates  rise,  or  benefit  rates 
fall,  in  moving  from  a  lower  to  a  higher  income  class,  the  pattern  of  rates  will  be 


"Because  families  and  individuals  customarily  think  of  income  in  money  terms,  we  relate 
our  following  discussion  of  effective  rates  of  taxation  (burden),  expenditure  (benefit), 
and  net  fiscal  incidence  to  the  money-income  classification  of  Ontario  residents.  It 
should  nevertheless  be  clearly  understood  that  an  "effective"  rate  for  any  money- 
income  class  is  the  rate  that  prevails  in  relation  to  the  adjusted  broad  income  of  the 
money-income  class. 

154 


Chapter  5 :  Paragraphs  28-30 


^ 


O     ;2 

D    S 
pq 


o 

t 

o 

s 

CI 

o 

cT 

"« 

5 

<3 

^ 

0\ 

^ 

Ov 

&^ 

^ 

0\ 

O 

0\ 

o 

O 

^ 

<r 

So* 


Ci  <o  o  o  oo 
rn  — <  O  rn  lo  O 
OOSOs<N  vo  rN 
00  <N  00  00        OO 


r-;  OS  "ofN  p  o 
fi  00  f«i  t-^  a\  <N 

VD  Tf  Tt  OO  Tj- 

O        ro  <N 


'-;  r- OO  O  r^  r-l     -H 

vo  ooooov  t~  ri 
>o  m  r~  ^  -H  -H 


ro  (N  v^  -^  -^  — 


r«^  00  "O  vo  T}-  O 

ON  <N  vb  w^  OS  O 
r^  •^  m  00      o 


ro  </-)  W-)  fS  OO  -^ 
t^  ON  <N  00  Tt  0\ 

00  -"^  in  r~      r- 


ro  !-•  >n  00  w-1  in 
v£>  1-^  ON  -H  <N  o6 

ON  Tj-  o  <n      '-^ 


p  fs  r~;  ooo\  -^ 
r-^  <n  in  ON  '  vd 
O       t^— I       o 


o 

p 

o 

NO 

rn 
m 

in 

ro 

r«i 

NO 

ON 

oo 

oo 

^^ 

O 

,._^ 

ri 
m 
<n 

vd 

vo_ 

CM 

NO 

00 

tj- 

ON 

ON 

ON 

en 

VO 

„ 

r~ 

>n 

<n 

NO 

00 

in 

■* 

00 

CN 

«n 

oo 

rj 

00 

ro 

■* 

1^ 

VO 

en 
en 

On 
m 

NO 

r- 

V£> 

rn 

vd 

3 

OOO      O  f*^  O  in  ■^ 


(/)    I    ci 
9^  C  >  S 


>  o  y 
»  o.S 

I  fa  a. 
!  ^  E 

i«.S 


c«   3   1)   o 

4> ^  0.5 


c  o 


3^  -S 


=  <u 


T3   O   !>   C 


u 


<u  c 


m  ON  NO 
f*^  f*^  On 
fN<N  -^ 


'<^  .^  ^^  m  in 

On  in  -^  <^  r<i 


vo  --  r-;  oo  r- 

On  r-  f^  On  O 
in<N  <N  Tt  On 

'-<  oo<n 


On  <^  p        p  «  p  ■^  NO 

Tt  in  O       O  K  OS  — ^  rn 

<N  <N  CO        -H        NO  — <  m 

^  00  r~ 


O  r-  00  «n  o 

00  vd  --^  O  rn 
<N  On  m 
<N  OnO 


00  p  •*         NO  VO  00  00  (S 

-^  ri  ON      Ttroinr-^in 

-H  —  Tt  <N|  (-»  „ 

—  Tt  vo 


T^— ^ON 


en  in  O 
-^  -^  in 


rn  Tt  r^l 
f~;  t^  vd 


Tj-  00  •^  -^  00 

■^rjr-^  -^ON 

ON  00  O 

^^r^Tj- 


m  Tt  r4  m  oo 

Ttr^  oor^O 

m  vo  t~ 

—  —  m 


On  NO  -^  ■^  rn 

<^  ^  in  r~  r4 

fn  in  NO 


E 
^  g 

O  </i 
^S 

x>  ^ 

u  u 

E  ■" 

n  W 
x-^  fa 

^•2  2 

to  W  (J  '-' 
M  b  Ti 
C   O  4^  e 


p  5  o 


in 

<u 

3  is  •-" 


C    C-M- 
CQ   C   u 

w  E  o 


C 

60M 

u 

"O 

«  E 

c 

4^   <U 

CQ 

CX> 

E2 

u 

5  <u 

c 

^£ 

c 
u 

E 

c 

|E 
-  > 

CV- 

u 

a  o 

«--,':^  « 


*j     « 


sSbu 


J3 

•— 

T3 

c 

U 

3 

•o 

o 

■> 

o 

O 
P. 

3 

2 

CO 

O 

•o 

u 

•«-» 

c 

ea 

o 

c 

■o    E 


X)     o 


cj 

«N 

■^ 

en 

Ii 

in 

in 

'3 

_« 

J) 

E 

ii 

JO 

(A 

en 

H 

H 

u 

C 

en" 

en" 

C/5 

o 

c« 

2 

o 

O 

o 

as 

Ui 

•o 

■o 

U3 

0.) 

£ 

c 

c 

3 

pi 

OS 

fc! 

en 

^ 

^ 

3 
O 

I 

s 

SJ 

1/3 

M 

00 

155 


Incidence  of  Government  Revenue  and  Expenditure 


Effective 

tax  rate 

(%) 

20  I- 


Chart  5:1 

Effective  tax   (burden)   rates  of  provincial  and  municipal  governments  in 

Ontario,  1961 


15   h 

10 

5 


PROVINCIAL  GOVERNMENT 


under  $2000-  $3000-  $4000-  $5000-  $7000-  $10,000 

$2000  2999  3999  4999  6999  9999  and  over 

Family  income  class 


Effective 

tax  rate 

(%) 

20 


Effective 
tax  rate 

20 


15   h 

10 


MUNICIPAL  GOVERNMENT 


Effective 
tax  rate 

(%) 

20 


H    15 
10 


5 


5 


Effective 

tax  rate 

(%) 

20  I- 


15 


under 
$2000 


$2000-  $3000-  $4000-  $5000-  $7000-  $10,000 

2999  3999  4999  6999  9999  and  over 

Family  income  class 


COMBINED  PROVINCIAL  AND  MUNICIPAL  GOVERNMENTS 


Effective 
tax  rate 

(%) 
-1    20 


$3000-  $4000-  $5000- 

3999  4999  6999 

Family  income  class 


$7000-  $10,000 

9999  and  over 


under  $2000- 

$2000  2999 

Source:  Table  5:6 

Thcic   rales   arc   based  on    the   allocation   holh   of   lax    revenues   and    of   "other"   revenues.    See  Tabic  5:6. 


156 


Chapter  5:  Paragraph  31 

Table  5:6 

EFFECTIVE  REVENUE  RATES   FOR  SELECTED  GOVERNMENTS  IN  CANADA,  1961 

(percentage  of  adjusted  broad  income) 

Family  Money  Income  Class 

Under      $2,000-     $3,000-  $4,000-  $5,000-  $7,000-  $10,000 

$2,000       2,999        3,999  4,999  6,999  9,999    and  over 
Provincial  Revenues  (Ontario) 

Personal  income  tax 0.1            0.1            0.5  0.7  1.2  1.3  1.8 

Corporation  income  tax 0.5            0.4           0.4  0.4  0.4  0.4  1.0 

General  sales  tax 0.9           0.9            1.2  1.1  1.2  1.3  0.9 

Highway-user  revenues 0.5            0.7            1.1  1.4  1.5  1.5  1.1 

Excise  taxes 0.6           0.3            0.7  0.8  0.8  0.9  0.5 

Succession  duties 2.1 

Natural-resource  revenue 0.2           0.1            0.1  0.1  0.1  0.1  0.3 

Social  insurance  contributions      0.3            0.4           0.6  0.6  0.7  0.7  0.5 

Hospital  premiums 2.1            1.1            1.0  0.9  0.8  0.6  0.3 

Other  taxes  and  misc.  revenue      0.4           0.3            0.3  0.3  0.3  0.3  0.3 

Total 5.6           4.3            5.9  6.3  7.0  7.1  8.8 

Municipal  Revenues  (Ontario) 

Property  tax 7.0            3.9            4.1  3.8  3.6  3.2  3.4 

Business  tax 0.3            0.2           0.3  0.2  0.2  0.2  0.4 

Miscellaneous  revenue 0.7 04 04 04 04 03 0.3 

Total 8.0            4.5            4.8  4.4  4.2  3.7  4.1 

Total  Ontario  Provincial  and 

Municipal  Revenue 13.6            8.8          107  10.7  11.2  108  12.9 

Provincial  and  Municipal  Revenue 

(Other  than  Ontario) 2.5            2.0           2.1  1.9  1.9  2.0  4.7 

Total  Provincial  and  Municipal 

Revenue  (All  Canada) 16.1          108          12.8  12.6  13.1  12.8  17.6 

Federal  Revenues 

Personal  income  tax 0.8            1.0            3.4  4.8  8.1  9.3  12.6 

Corporation  income  tax 3.1            2.6            2.7  2.3  2.3  2.5  7.3 

General  sales  tax 2.8            2.4            3.1  3.3  3.4  3.3  2.4 

Other  excises 1.7            1.3            1.8  1.8  1.9  1.6  0.9 

Estate  tax 1-8 

Social  insurance  contributions      1.3            1.9            2.8  2.8  1.3  0.8  0.6 

Import  duties 2.0            1.4            1.7  1.7  1.7  1.6  1.1 

Miscellaneous  revenue 0.5            0.4           0.3  0.3  0.3  0.3  0.4 

Total 12.2          11.0          15.8  17.0  19.0  19.4  27.1 

Total  Government  Revenues....     28.3          21.8          28.6  29.6  32.1  32.2  44.7 

Source :  J.  A.  Johnson,  Incidence  of  Government  Revenues  and  Expenditures. 


described  as  progressive.  Conversely,  should  effective  tax  rates  fall,  or  benefit  rates 
rise,  in  moving  from  a  lower  to  a  higher  income  class,  the  pattern  will  be  described 
as  regressive,  since  such  patterns  imply  increased  inequality  of  income  distribution. 
In  addition  to  indicating  the  effective  tax  rates  on  Ontario  residents  for  each  source 
of  revenue  at  each  of  the  three  levels  of  government  and  for  all  three  levels 
combined.  Table  5:6  presents  the  effective  rates  on  Ontario  residents  for  all 
provincial  and  municipal  sources  combined,  for  all  federal  sources,  and  for  all 
sources  for  all  levels  of  government  combined. 


31.  An  examination  of  the  effective  combined  provincial  tax  rate  reveals 
that,  apart  from  a  regressive  fall  between  the  two  lowest  income  classes,  the 
structure  is  mildly  progressive.   This  is  in  contrast  to  the  municipal  rate  structure, 

157 


Incidence  of  Government  Revenue  and  Expenditure 

the  burden  pattern  of  which  is  decidedly  regressive,  with  the  effective  rates  falling 
from  8.0  per  cent  in  the  lowest  income  class  to  4.1  per  cent  in  the  highest  class. 
This  regressiveness  is  largely  explained  by  the  very  high  proportion  of  income  that 
low-income  families  are  forced  to  spend  upon  accommodation,  an  expenditure 
that  is  heavily  burdened  by  the  real  property  tax.  Chart  5 : 1  reveals  that  when  the 
provincial  and  municipal  burdens  are  combined,  a  somewhat  U-shaped  distribution 
emerges,  with  high  rates  for  the  lowest  and  highest  income  classes,  and  more  modest 
rates  for  the  intervening  classes.  This  particular  configuration  of  rates  is  largely 
attributable  to  the  regressiveness  of  the  property  tax  at  low-income  levels  and  to 
the  progressiveness  of  the  corporate  and  personal  income  taxes  at  high-income 
levels.  The  addition  of  the  revenue  burdens  imported  into  Ontario  from  other 
provincial  and  municipal  tax  jurisdictions  does  not  alter  the  basic  nature  of  this 
U-shaped  pattern,  merely  raising  its  level  in  each  income  class.  This  increase  is 
most  significant  for  the  highest  income  class,  where  stock  ownership  by  Ontario 
residents  causes  substantial  importation  of  business  taxes,  the  total  effective  rate 
being  raised  from  12.9  to  17.6  per  cent. 

32.  Given  the  federal  government's  heavy  reliance  upon  corporate  and 
personal  income  taxation,  it  is  not  surprising  that  its  combined  effective  rate  pattern 
is  more  progressive  than  those  of  the  other  two  levels  of  government.  Various 
federal  taxes  levied  on  consumption  nevertheless  give  rise  to  some  regression 
between  the  two  lowest  income  classes,  the  effective  rate  being  12.2  per  cent  in  the 
lowest  income  class  and  11.0  per  cent  in  the  next.  This  regressiveness  results  from 
people  in  the  lowest  income  class  spending  proportionately  more  of  their  incomes 
on  goods  subject  to  consumption  taxes.  It  is  aggravated  by  a  greater  tendency  on 
the  part  of  these  families  to  spend  in  excess  of  their  incomes  compared  to  people 
in  higher  income  classes.  From  the  low  point  of  11.0  per  cent,  the  effective  rate 
continuously  rises  for  successive  income  classes  and  reaches  27.1  per  cent  for  those 
with  money  incomes  in  excess  of  $10,000. 

33.  When  all  three  levels  of  government  are  combined,  including  the  taxes 
paid  by  Ontario  residents  to  other  provincial  and  municipal  governments,  the  rate 
pattern  that  emerges  is  progressive  for  all  but  the  lowest  income  ranges.  The 
substantial  reduction  of  the  overall  effective  rate  between  the  lowest  and  second- 
lowest  income  classes  (from  28.3  per  cent  to  21.8  per  cent)  is  not  necessarily 
evidence  of  an  inappropriate  tax  structure.  Viewed  in  isolation,  both  the  level  and 
pattern  of  these  rates  appear  to  be  unsatisfactory,  but  when  taken  in  conjunction 
with  the  expenditure  benefits  conferred  upon  the  members  of  these  income  classes, 
the  net  effect  of  government  fiscal  activities  appears  in  quite  a  different  light.  It  is 
therefore  necessary  to  defer  judgment  until  the  pattern  of  benefit  rates  has  been 
examined  and  combined  with  the  tax  rate  pattern. 

EFFECTIVE  BENEFIT  RATES 

34.  Just  as  the  over-all  pattern  of  effective  tax  rates  is  with  few  exceptions 
progressive,  so  too  is  that  of  effective  benefit  rates.  A  comparison  of  the  effective 
benefit  rates  of  each  of  the  three  levels  of  government,  as  shown  in  Table  5:7, 
reveals  an  even  greater  degree  of  similarity  than  that  found  in  the  effective  tax 

158 


Chapter  5 :  Paragraphs  32-34 


Chart  5:2 

Effective  expenditure  (benefit)  rates  of  provincial  and  municipal  governments 

in  Ontario,  1961 


Effective 

expenditure 

rate 

(%) 

15 


Effective 

expenditure 

rate 

(%) 


10 


Effective 

expenditure 

rate 

(%) 

15 


10 


PROVINCIAL  GOVERNMENT 

1 

under  $2000-  $3000-  $4000-  $5000-  $7000-  $10,000 

$2000  2999  3999  4999  6999  9999  and  over 

Family  income  class 


Effective 

expenditure 

rate 

(%) 

15 


MUNICIPAL  GOVERNMENT 

1 

1 

under  $2000-  $3000-  $4000-  $5000-  $7000-  $10,000 

$2000  2999  3999  4999  6999  9999  and  over 

Family  income  class 


EfTeclive 

expenditure 

rate 


(%) 


30 

25    - 
20 
15 
10 
5   h 


Effective 

expenditure 

rate 

(%) 


25 


COMBINED  PROVINCIAL  AND  MUNICIPAL  GOVERNMENTS 

1 

1 

- 

- 

under 
$2000 

$2000- 
2999 

$3000-            $4000-            $5000- 

3999              4999               6999 

Family  income  class 

$7000- 
9999 

$10,000 
and  over 

:  Table  5: 7 

159 


Incidence  of  Government  Revenue  and  Expenditure 

Table  5:7 

EFFECTIVE  EXPENDITURE  RATES  FOR  SELECTED  GOVERNMENTS  IN  CANADA,  1961 
(percentage  of  adjusted  broad  income) 

Family  Money  Income  Class 

Under  $2,000-  $3,000-  $4,000-  55,000-  $7,000-  $10,000 

$2,000  2,999  3,999  4,999  6,999  9,999  and  over 
Provincial  Expenditures  (Ontario) 

Highways,  roads  and  bridges         1.2  1.2  1.5  1.6  1.8  1.6  1.2 

Education 1.7  2.2  2.9  3.3  2.7  2.0  1.5 

Health  and  sanitation 4.0  2.5  2.6  2.5  2.2  1.6  0.8 

Interest 0.3  0.1  0.1  0.1  0.1  0.1  0.2 

Social  welfare 4.6  2.4  1.2  0.9  0.7  0.7  0.4 

Agriculture 0.7  0.2  0.1  0.1  —  —  — 

General  expenditures 1.9 L2 K2 M LO 0^9 l.Q 

Total 14.4  9.8  9.6  9.6  8.5  6.9  5.1 

Municipal  Expenditures  (Ontario) 

Highways,  roads  and  bridges .  0.8  0.7  0.8  0.9  0.9  0.8  0.7 

Education 2.1  2.9  4.1  4.6  3.6  2.5  1.1 

Health  and  sanitation 2.6  1.4  1.3  1.1  1.0  0.8  0.4 

Interest 0.2  0.1  0.1  0.1  0.1  0.1  0.2 

Social  welfare 1.0  0.6  0.3  0.2  0.2  0.2  0.1 

General  expenditures 3.8 2J 22 2J L9 1/7 1.9 

Total 10.5  8.0  8.8  9.0  7.7  6.1  4.4 

Total  Ontario  Provincial  and 

Municipal  Expenditures 24.9  17.8  18.4  18.6  16.2  13.0  9.5 

Provincial  and  Municipal 

Expenditures  (Other  than 

Ontario) 1.0  0.8  0.8  0.7  0.7  0.8  2.5 

Total  Provincial  and  Municipal 

Expenditures  (All  Canada) . . .     25.9  18.6  19.2  19.3  16.9  13.8  12.0 

Federal  Expenditures 

Highways,  roads  and  bridges.  0.3  0.2  0.3  0.3  0.3  0.3  0.2 

Other  transportation 1.0  0.7  0.9  0.7  0.7  0.7  0.5 

Education 0.2  0.3  0.3  0.4  0.3  0.3  0.4 

Health  and  sanitation 2.2  1.4  1.4  1.4  1.2  0.8  0.4 

Interest 4.5  2.2  1.5  1.3  1.6  1.8  3.6 

Social  welfare 33.8  13.5  7.5  6.0  5.2  4.3  2.2 

Agriculture 1.5  2.6  2.0  1.0  0.7  0.6  0.9 

General  expenditures 13.7  8.7  8.5  7.8  7.2  6.5  10.9 

Total 57.2  29.6  22.4  18.9  17.2  15.3  19.1 

Total  Government  Expenditures    83.1  48.2  41.6  38.2  34.1  29.1  31.1 

Source :  J.  A.  Johnson,  Incidence  of  Government  Revenues  and  Expenditures. 

rates.  For  each  level  of  government  the  basic  pattern  is  progressive,  with  benefit 
rates  falling  as  income  increases.  Only  in  two  instances  does  some  regression 
occur,  one  in  the  federal  and  one  in  the  municipal  structure. 

35.  As  Table  5:7  indicates,  for  all  three  levels  of  government  combined,  and 
including  benefits  enjoyed  by  Ontario  residents  but  provided  by  other  provincial 
and  municipal  governments,  the  progression  in  benefits  is  quite  pronounced,  the 
effective  rate  falling  from  83.1  per  cent  in  the  lowest  income  class  to  31.1  per  cent 
in  the  highest.  Regression  is  encountered  only  as  between  the  highest  income 
classes.  If  federal  general  governmental  expenditures  were  omitted,  even  this 
regression  would  be  eliminated,  because  it  is  mainly  attributable  to  having  allocated 
one-quarter  of  federal  general  expenditures  in  proportion  to  dividend  income. 

160 


I 


Chapter  5:  Paragraphs  35-40 

36.  The  provincial  pattern  of  benefit  rates  is  progressive  over  all  income 
classes,  the  actual  rates  varying  between  14.4  per  cent  in  the  lowest  income  class 
and  5.1  per  cent  in  the  highest.  The  total  municipal  pattern  is  somewhat  less 
regular,  with  some  regression  being  encountered  in  the  middle  income  classes. 
Here  the  main  explanation  is  found  in  the  pattern  of  education  benefits,  these  in 
turn  being  determined  by  the  incidence  of  age  distribution  of  children  among  the 
various  classes.  These  effective  benefit  rates  for  the  provincial  and  municipal 
governments  in  Ontario  are  presented  pictorially  in  Chart  5:2. 

37.  An  examination  of  individual  categories  of  expenditure  reveals  that  social 
welfare  expenditures  are  the  most  important  source  of  progression  in  benefit  rates. 
This  is  especially  true  at  the  federal  level,  where  these  expenditures  account  for 
33.8  per  cent  of  the  adjusted  broad  income  of  the  lowest  income  classes  but  only 
2.2  per  cent  of  those  with  money  incomes  of  $10,000  or  more.  For  the  provincial 
and  municipal  levels  of  government,  the  benefit  rates  from  welfare  expenditure  are 
lower  but  the  relative  differences  between  the  highest  and  lowest  income  classes  are 
comparable.  Another  source  of  progression  in  benefit  rates,  especially  at  provincial 
and  municipal  levels,  is  expenditure  on  health  and  sanitation. 

THE  CONCEPT  OF  NET  FISCAL  INCIDENCE 

38.  While  it  is  very  useful  to  determine  effective  tax  and  benefit  rates  for  each 
income  class  of  Ontario  residents,  we  have  already  warned  that  the  appraisal  of 
these  rates  requires  an  examination  of  their  net  impact.  For  this  purpose,  we  have 
constructed  a  rate  of  net  fiscal  incidence  for  each  income  class,  this  being  obtained 
by  subtracting  the  effective  tax  rate  of  the  class  from  the  effective  benefit  rate. 
Where  the  benefit  rate  exceeds  the  tax  rate,  the  resulting  rate  of  net  fiscal  incidence 
is  positive  and  government,  on  balance,  is  causing  a  redistribution  of  income  in 
favour  of  the  members  of  those  income  classes  enjoying  positive  rates.  On  the 
other  hand,  where  taxes  exceed  benefits,  the  rate  of  net  fiscal  incidence  is  negative, 
the  fiscal  process  redistributing  income  away  from  the  members  of  those  income 
classes  subject  to  negative  rates. 

39.  If  rates  of  net  fiscal  incidence  are  positive  but  decrease  with  income  and 
possibly  become  negative  at  higher  income  levels,  the  pattern  of  rates  is  described 
as  progressive.  Similarly,  where  rates  are  negative  and  fall  to  even  larger  negative 
values  as  income  rises,  the  pattern  is  described  as  progressive.  Conversely,  patterns 
involving  positive  net  rates  that  increase  with  income,  or  negative  net  rates  that 
assume  smaller  negative  values,  or  even  become  positive  as  income  increases,  are 
described  as  regressive.  It  is  consistent  with  our  earlier  usage  that  the  terms 
"progressive"  and  "regressive"  describe  rates  of  net  fiscal  incidence  that  respectively 
decrease  and  increase  the  inequality  of  income  distribution. 

40.  Before  we  present  and  analyse  our  findings  concerning  the  rates  of  net 
fiscal  incidence  among  Ontario  residents,  we  wish  to  review  several  of  their 
limitations.  First  and  possibly  most  important,  the  amount  of  redistribution 
indicated  by  the  net  rates  is  not  a  comprehensive  measure  of  the  redistributive 
impact  of  all  government  policies.  In  arriving  at  these  rates,  no  allowance  whatever 

161 


Incidence  of  Government  Revenue  and  Expenditure 

is  made  for  the  redistribution  undoubtedly  occasioned  by  monetary  policy,  tariff 
policy,  combines  policy,  minimum  wage  legislation  and  a  myriad  of  other 
governmental  activities.  A  second  limitation  is  that  with  respect  to  the  revenue 
and  expenditure  programs  that  we  have  explicitly  examined  in  our  study,  it  is  only 
the  actual  monetary  receipts  and  outlays  that  have  been  taken  into  consideration. 
Changes  in  the  level  and  distribution  of  income  caused  by  the  adjustments  to  these 
programs  have  been  ignored.  While  it  would  be  highly  desirable  to  allow  for  the 
distributive  effects  of  all  of  these  factors,  the  present  state  of  economic  theory  and 
empirical  research  simply  does  not  permit  this  to  be  done.  It  should  also  be  kept 
in  mind  that  our  results  have  been  obtained  only  with  the  aid  of  a  formidable 
array  of  assumptions  which  are  listed  as  an  Appendix  to  this  chapter.  While  we 
hope  that  we  have  in  each  circumstance  chosen  the  most  reasonable  assumptions, 
errors  of  judgment  can  by  no  means  be  ruled  out.  Our  results  must  therefore  be 
used  with  caution. 

41.  In  interpreting  the  rates  of  net  fiscal  incidence  on  Ontario  residents,  the 
reader  should  keep  in  mind  that  the  total  expenditure  benefits  imputed  to  the 
residents  of  the  province  exceed  the  tax  burdens  imputed  to  them.  In  consequence, 
the  general  level  of  rates  of  net  fiscal  incidence  is  higher  than  it  would  have  been 
if  benefits  had  been  precisely  matched  by  taxes,  and  more  income  classes  appear  to 
be  the  beneficiaries  of  fiscal  redistribution  than  would  have  if  benefits  and  burdens 
had  been  equal.  The  discrepancy  between  total  benefits  and  total  burdens  is  thus 
significant  in  interpreting  net  fiscal  incidence  and  it  warrants  some  explanatory 
comment. 

42.  In  large  part,  the  excess  of  benefits  over  burdens  is  attributable  to  the 
deficit  financing  practised  by  the  three  levels  of  government  in  1961.  The  deficits 
incurred  by  these  governments  permitted  them  to  provide  expenditure  benefits  which 
exceeded  their  revenues  and  Ontario  residents  were  among  the  beneficiaries  of 
these  excesses.  It  has  been  estimated  that  the  net  benefits  gained  by  the  residents 
of  Ontario  from  the  federal,  Ontario  provincial,  and  Ontario  municipal  governments 
were  $183.6  million,  $151.3  million,  and  $325.6  milHon  respectively.  These 
amounts  reflected,  in  addition  to  the  effects  of  the  budgetary  deficits,  the  particular 
nature  of  the  tax  and  expenditure  programs  provided  by  the  governments. 

43.  The  combined  effect  of  these  factors  caused  the  benefits  enjoyed  by 
Ontario  residents  to  exceed  their  tax  and  other  burdens  by  $660.5  million 
($183.6  million  +  $151.3  million  +  $325.6  million).  On  the  other  hand,  the 
burdens  exported  by  other  provincial  and  municipal  jurisdictions  to  Ontario  resi- 
dents exceeded  by  $160.6  million  the  benefits  those  governments  exported  to 
Ontario  residents.  In  consequence,  the  net  excess  of  benefits  over  burdens,  for 
Ontario  residents,  was  $499.9  million  ($660.5  million — $160.6  million).  This  is 
the  measure  of  the  net  excess  implicit  in  the  pattern  of  net  fiscal  incidence  among 
our  family  income  classes,  which  causes  the  rates  of  this  incidence  to  be  somewhat 
higher  than  they  would  have  been  had  total  benefits  and  total  burdens  been  equal. 

44.  Although  we  have  derived  the  net  tax  burdens  exported  from  other 
provincial  and  municipal  jurisdictions  to  Ontario  residents,  we  have  made  no 

162 


Chapter  5:  Paragraphs  41-46 

TABLE  5:8 

"NET  FISCAL  INCIDENCE"  OF  THE  REVENUE  AND 

EXPENDITURE  PROGRAMS  OF  SELECTED  GOVERNMENTS  IN  CANADA,  1961 

(percentage  of  adjusted  broad  income) 

Family  Money  Income  Class 

Under     $2,000-     $3,000-     $4,000-     $5,000-     $7,000-    $10,000 
$2,000       2,999        3,999        4,999        6,999        9,999     and  over 

Provincial  (Ontario) 8.8  5.5  3.7  3.3  1.5  -.2        -3.7 

Municipal  (Ontario) 2.5  3.5  4.0  4.6  3.5  2.4  .3 

Provincial  and  Municipal 

(Ontario) 11.3  9.0  7.7  7.9  5.0  2.2         -3.4 

Federal 45.0  18.6  6.6  1.9        -1.8        -4.1         -8.0 

Provincial  and  Municipal  (Other 

than  in  Ontario) -1.5         -1.2         -1.3         -1.2         -1.2         -1.2         -2.2 


Total 54.8        26.4  13.0  8.6  2.0        -3.1       -13.6 

Source :  J.  A.  Johnson,  Incidence  of  Government  Revenues  and  Expenditures. 

estimate  of  either  the  burdens  or  the  benefits  exported  from  Ontario  to  the 
residents  of  these  jurisdictions.  In  consequence,  it  cannot  be  concluded  that 
Ontario  is  necessarily  a  net  contributor  in  its  fiscal  relations  with  the  other 
provinces  and  their  municipalities.  Since  this  study  is  concerned  with  the  net  fiscal 
incidence  for  Ontario  residents,  these  burdens  and  benefits  exported  from  Ontario 
have  not  entered  into  our  calculations. 

THE  PATTERN  OF  NET  FISCAL  INCIDENCE  AMONG  ONTARIO  RESIDENTS 

45.  Looking  first  at  the  pattern  of  net  fiscal  incidence  for  all  levels  of 
government  combined,  it  is  immediately  apparent  that  the  effective  rate  structure  is 
strongly  progressive,  the  actual  rates  falling  from  a  level  of  54.8  per  cent  in  the 
lowest  income  class  to  —13.6  per  cent  in  the  highest  income  class.  Because  a 
positive  rate  of  net  fiscal  incidence  indicates  a  net  gain  from  budgetary  redistribu- 
tion, and  a  negative  rate  indicates  a  loss,  it  is  evident  that  government  as  a  whole 
occasions  a  substantial  redistribution  of  income  within  Ontario.  Although  Table 
5:8  does  not  indicate  the  precise  income  level  at  which  the  rate  of  net  fiscal 
incidence  becomes  zero,  it  appears  that  typical  families  or  unattached  individuals 
with  money  incomes  not  exceeding  $7,000  per  annum  are  net  beneficiaries  of 
budgetary  redistribution.  Those  with  annual  money  incomes  in  excess  of  this 
watershed  level  are  net  contributors.  The  lack  of  a  more  detailed  classification  of 
data  compelled  us  to  make  use  of  an  open-ended  "$10,000  and  over"  class  at  the 
upper  end  of  the  money-income  scale.  Had  it  been  possible  to  subdivide  this  class, 
the  progressiveness  of  the  net  fiscal  incidence  would  have  been  even  more  forcefully 
demonstrated. 

46.  An  examination  of  the  rates  of  net  fiscal  incidence  for  the  several  levels 
of  government  in  Canada  reveals  that  the  federal  government  is  the  primary  source 
of  progression  in  the  composite  picture.  It  will  be  recalled  from  our  examination 
of  effective  tax  and  benefit  rates  that  this  government  relies  heavily  on  income 
taxation  and  that  social  welfare  programs  figure  prominently  among  its  expenditures. 

163 


Incidence  of  Government  Revenue  and  Expenditure 


Chart  5:3 
Net  fiscal  incidence  rates,  1961 


Effective 
net  benefit 

rate 

(%) 
15 


(A  negative  "effective  net  benefit"  rale   measures   the   "effective   net  burden"   borne   by   the 
relevant  family  income  class.) 


PROVINCIAL  government 

1 

1          1 

Effective 

net  benefit 

rate 

(%) 


under 
$2000 


$2000- 
2999 


Effective 

net  benefit 

rate 

(%) 

15   1- 


$3000-  $4000-  $5000-  $7000- 

3999  4999  6999  9999 

Family  income  class 


MUNICIPAL  government 


$10,000 
and  over 


Effective 

net  benefit 

rate 

(%) 

15 


10 


Effective 
net  benefit 

rate 

(%) 
20 


under  $2000-  $3000-  $4000-  $5000-  $7000- 

$2000  2999  3999  4999  6999  9999 

Family  income  class 


COMBINED  PROVINCIAL  AND  MUNICIPAL  GOVERNMENTS 


$10,000 
and  over 


Effective 

net  benefit 

rate 

(%) 

-1   20 


-    15 
10 
5 


under 


$2000-  $3000-  $4000-  $5000-  $7000-  $10,000 

2999  3999  4999  6999  9999  and  over 

Family  income  class 


Source:  Table  5:8 


164 


Chapter  5 :  Paragraphs  47-48 

The  substantial  progression  of  the  federal  net  incidence  rates  (which  fall  from  45.0 
per  cent  to  —8.0  per  cent  in  moving  from  the  lowest  to  the  highest  money-income 
class )  is  thus  hardly  surprising.  A  further,  more  modest  contribution  to  progression 
is  made  by  the  Ontario  provincial  revenue  and  expenditure  programs,  their  net 
incidence  ranging  from  8.8  per  cent  at  the  lowest  end  of  the  income  scale  to  —3.7 
per  cent  at  the  upper  end.  It  is  only  the  municipal  net  rates  that  display  regression, 
and  these  rise  regressively  over  the  income  range  spanned  by  the  four  lowest 
income  classes.  Thereafter,  municipal  net  incidence  rates  fall  but  they  maintain 
positive  values  for  all  income  classes.'^  Apart  from  a  slight,  regressive  inversion 
between  the  third  and  fourth  money  income  classes,  the  combined  Ontario 
provincial-municipal  pattern  of  net  rates  is  progressive,  the  actual  rates  ranging 
from  11.3  per  cent  in  the  lowest  money-income  class  to  — 3.4  per  cent  in  the 
highest.  These  patterns  of  provincial  and  municipal  net  fiscal  incidence  in  Ontario 
are  pictured  in  Chart  5:3.  A  similar  pattern  is  maintained  at  a  lower  absolute  level 
when  the  combined  Ontario  provincial-municipal  net  rates  are  adjusted  to  reflect 
the  importation  of  benefits  and  burdens  from  other  provincial  and  municipal 
jurisdictions. 

GENERAL  CONCLUSIONS 

47.  Although  our  study  has  indicated  a  regressive  structure  of  effective  tax 
rates  in  the  lower  income  classes  of  Ontario,  with  rates  that  will  be  regarded  by 
many  as  surprisingly  high,  the  picture  changes  markedly  for  these  groups  when  the 
distribution  of  the  benefits  from  government  expenditures  is  considered.  Here  we 
have  found  that  the  expenditure  structure  heavily  favours  low  income  recipients 
and  the  pattern  of  net  expenditure  rates  more  than  offsets  the  regressiveness  of  the 
net  tax  rates.  As  a  consequence,  substantial  net  benefits  are  conveyed,  on  balance, 
to  those  Ontario  families  and  unattached  individuals  who  are  in  receipt  of  relatively 
low  annual  incomes. 

48.  It  is  interesting  to  speculate  on  the  implications  of  changes  in  the  relative 
size  of  the  financial  operations  of  the  different  levels  of  government  in  the  light  of 
our  net  fiscal  incidence  findings.  Because  the  tax  and  expenditure  programs  of  the 
federal  government  are  at  present  the  primary  source  of  progressiveness  in  the  total 
Canadian  fiscal  system,  any  reduction  in  the  relative  importance  of  the  federal 
government's  fiscal  operations  will,  if  a  diminution  of  progression  is  to  be  avoided, 
need  to  be  accompanied  by  an  increased  reliance  upon  progressive  tax  sources  and 
expenditure  programs  by  the  other  levels  of  government.  In  this  connection,  the 
continuing  use  of  the  personal  income  tax  abatement  technique,  as  a  means  of 
transferring  tax  capacity  from  the  federal  to  the  provincial  governments  in  Canada, 
has  in  fact  lessened  the  progressiveness  of  the  federal  tax  system  and  increased  that 
of  the  provinces.  Given  the  present  narrow  and  regressive  municipal  tax  base,  it  is 

'In  order  to  avoid  double  counting,  unconditional  intergovernmental  grants  are  shown 
as  expenditures  only  of  the  recipient  governments.  Since  there  is  no  offsetting  tax 
burden  at  the  recipient  level  (the  funds  having  been  raised  by  the  grantor),  the  receipt 
of  these  grants  is  similar  in  effect  to  a  budgetary  deficit,  both  tending  to  raise  the  rates 
of  net  fiscal  incidence.  For  municipalities,  grants  and  deficits  are  sufficiently  large  to 
cause  the  net  incidence  rates  to  be  positive  in  all  income  classes. 

165 


Incidence  of  Government  Revenue  and  Expenditure 

very  difficult  for  the  municipalities  to  promote  or  achieve  progression.  It  is  there- 
fore highly  probable  that  as  provincial  revenue  and  expenditure  requirements  con- 
tinue to  grow  more  rapidly  than  those  of  the  federal  government,  the  primary 
burden  of  maintaining  the  progressiveness  of  the  Canadian  fiscal  system  will  fall 
upon  the  government  of  Ontario  and  those  of  the  other  provinces. 

49.  We  begin  this  chapter  by  expressing  the  view  that  a  reliable  knowledge 
of  the  net  incidence  of  the  revenue  and  expenditure  patterns  of  the  several  levels 
of  government  in  Canada  is  an  indispensable  prerequisite  to  the  attainment  of 
greater  fiscal  equity,  as  among  various  income  groups.  The  rapidly  changing 
patterns  of  government  revenue  and  expenditure  within  this  country  therefore 
necessitate  a  program  of  continuous  research  if  relevant  and  timely  information 
relating  to  fiscal  incidence  is  to  be  available  in  the  formulation  of  the  most  appro- 
priate tax  and  expenditure  policies.  We,  therefore,  strongly  urge  the  Ontario 
government  to  institute  such  a  program. 


166 


Chapter  5 :  Paragraph  49-Appendix 

Appendix  to  Chapter  5 

ASSUMPTIONS  REGARDING  THE  SHIFTING  AND 
INCIDENCE  OF  MAJOR  REVENUE  SOURCES^ 

The  shifting  and  incidence  assumptions  that  have  been  used  in  allocating  tax 
burdens  to  the  various  economic  groups  are  as  follows: 

(1)  Personal  income  tax:  This  tax  is  assumed  to  be  borne  by  those  upon 
whom  it  is  levied;  i.e.,  it  is  assumed  that  there  is  no  shifting. 

(2)  Corporate  income  tax:  It  is  assumed  that  one-half  of  the  burden  falls 
upon  capital,  and  so  on  stockholders,  and  that  the  remaining  half  is 
shifted  forward  to  consumers  in  the  form  of  higher  prices  for  the  output 
of  the  corporate  sector. 

(3)  Commodity  taxes:  This  category  includes  federal  and  provincial  sales 
taxes  and  the  various  specific  excise  taxes.  For  each,  the  assumption  is 
that  the  taxes  are  fully  shifted  forward,  falling  upon  the  various  users  of 
the  taxed  items  in  proportion  to  their  expenditures  upon  them. 

(4)  Selective  excise  taxes:  This  group  includes,  at  the  provincial  level,  the 
hospitals  tax,  race  tracks  tax,  revenues  from  the  sale  of  liquor  Ucences 
and  profits  from  the  governmental  sale  of  liquor.  While  these  last  two 
sources  of  revenue  are  not  taxes,  they  may  be  treated  analogously  to 
excise  taxes  because  they  strike  specific  types  of  products  and  are  used  in 
lieu  of  excises  on  these  products.  The  federal  revenue  sources  included 
in  this  class  are  the  excise  taxes  on  liquor,  tobacco,  automobiles, ^  and 
other  miscellaneous  commodities.  It  is  assumed  that  all  these  levies 
are  fully  shifted  forward,  to  be  borne  by  consumers  in  proportion  to 
their  expenditures  upon  the  taxed  items. 

(5)  Import  duties:  As  with  other  commodity  taxes,  these  are  assumed  to 
be  shifted  forward  to  consumers,  in  the  form  of  higher  prices. 

(6)  Highway-user  revenues:  Included  in  this  category  are  the  provincial 
gasoline  and  other  motor  vehicle  fuel  taxes,  and  motor  vehicle  registra- 
tion fees.  It  is  assumed  that  taxes  and  fees  paid  by  commercial  vehicle 
operators  should  be  treated  as  costs  of  production  and  therefore  passed 
on  to  consumers  in  proportion  to  their  expenditures.  Private  passenger 
vehicle  owners  are  assumed  to  bear  the  fuel  taxes  and  fees  incurred  in 
respect  of  these  vehicles.  The  burden  of  the  fuel  taxes  is  allocated  in 
proportion  to  the  costs  of  operating  automobiles,  and  that  of  the  fees  in 
proportion  to  purchases  of  automobiles. 

(7)  Succession  duties:  It  is  recognized  that  a  very  small  part  of  the  burden 
of  succession  duties  will  be  borne  by  non-residents.  Our  studies  suggest 
that  this  proportion  is  of  the  order  of  3  to  4  per  cent  of  the  duties,  and 


^The  reasons  underlying  the  selection  of  these  particular  assumptions  are  set  forth  in 
Johnson,  Incidence  of  Government  Revenues  and  Expenditures,  passim. 
^This  levy  was  repealed,  effective  June  21,  1961. 

167 


Incidence  of  Government  Revenue  and  Expenditure 

we  have  made  such  an  assumption  in  allocating  their  burden.  We  have 
further  assumed  that  the  burden  borne  domestically  falls  on  families  in 
the  $10,000  and  over  income  bracket.  While  not  strictly  precise,  this 
assumption  is  unlikely  to  introduce  any  serious  error  into  our  results. 

(8)  Property  taxes:  Here  the  basic  assumption  is  that  the  portion  of  the 
property  tax  levied  on  the  value  of  land  is  not  shifted  while,  with  the 
exception  of  owner-occupied  housing,  the  portion  on  improvements  is 
assumed  to  be  shifted  forward  in  the  form  of  higher  rentals  or  prices 
(these  being  occasioned  by  the  higher  costs  of  production,  the  tax  being 
viewed  as  a  cost).  The  burden  on  owner-occupied  housing  is  assumed  to 
remain  on  the  owner. 

(9)  Municipal  business  tax:  This  tax  is  treated  in  the  same  manner  as  the 
property  tax  on  business.  It  is  divided  between  land  and  improvements, 
with  the  portion  on  land  being  borne  by  the  owners,  and  the  portion  on 
improvements  borne  by  consumers. 

(10)  Natural-resources  revenue:  The  revenue  sources  included  in  this  category 
are  mining  and  logging  taxes,  stumpage  fees,  and  hunting  and  fishing 
licences.  Some  of  these  levies  are  treated  in  a  manner  similar  to  taxes  on 
profits,  others  are  held  to  enter  costs  of  production,  while  the  remainder 
are  assumed  to  be  borne  by  sportsmen. 

(11)  Social  insurance  contributions:  It  is  assumed  that  the  portion  of  these 
mandatory  contributions  paid  by  employees  is  borne  by  them.  Regarding 
the  portion  paid  by  employers,  a  distinction  is  made  between  government 
and  other  employers.  Government  pays  its  contributions  from  general 
revenue  and  thus  they  are  already  included  in  the  burdens  of  other  taxes. 
Of  the  contributions  paid  by  non-government  employers,  half  are 
assumed  to  be  shifted  forward  to  consumers  in  the  form  of  higher  prices, 
the  other  half  being  shifted  backward  to  employees  in  the  form  of  lower 
wages  than  would  otherwise  prevail, 

(12)  Other  taxes  and  revenues:  This  miscellaneous  category  includes  all  of 
the  remaining  revenues  collected  by  the  various  levels  of  government; 
excluded,  however,  are  some  of  the  income  of  Crown  corporations  and 
post  office  receipts.  Since  the  element  of  compulsion  is  typically  absent 
from  these  items  and  payments  tend  to  be  for  benefits  directly  rendered, 
only  deficits  or  surpluses  are  included  in  the  analysis.  Deficits  are 
treated  as  equivalent  to  expenditures,  and  surpluses  to  taxes.  For  the 
other  items,  the  allocating  assumptions  are  as  follows: 

(a)  Provincial   hospital  premiums   are   assumed  to  be   borne   by   the 
families  paying  them. 

(b)  Provincial  taxes  on  insurance  premiums  are  allocated  to  families 
in  proportion  to  their  expenditures  on  insurance. 

(c)  The  fire  marshal's  tax  and  land  transfer  taxes  are  assumed  to  be 
borne  in  proportion  to  the  property  tax  burden. 

168 


I 


Chapter  5:  Appendix 

(d)  Security   transfer   taxes   are   allocated  in   proportion   to   dividend 
income. 

(e)  The  miscellaneous  federal  revenue  items  are  dealt  with  in  a  manner 
comparable  to  similar  provincial  items. 

ASSUMPTIONS  REGARDING  THE  ALLOCATION  OF 
BENEFITS  FROM  MAJOR  EXPENDITURE  PROGRAMS^ 

The  costs  of  the  expenditure  programs  included  in  the  study  were  allocated  to 
the  various  economic  groups  and  income  classes  with  the  aid  of  the  following 
assumptions : 

-  (1)  Highway,  road,  street,  and  bridge  expenditures:  It  was  assumed  that 
these  expenditures  benefit  both  the  direct  users  who  own  passenger  or 
commercial  vehicles,  and  non-users  who  gain  by  the  provision  of  access 
to  their  property.  The  division  of  the  benefits  between  these  two  classes 
of  beneficiaries  was  accomplished  by  the  "earnings  credit  method",  while 
an  "incremental  cost"  approach  was  used  to  make  the  allocation  between 
passenger  and  commercial  vehicle  owners.^  Of  the  benefits  assigned 
property  owners  and  owners  of  commercial  vehicles,  25  per  cent  of  the 
former  and  all  of  the  latter  were  assumed  to  be  passed  on  to  consumers, 
in  the  form  of  lower  prices. 

(2)  Other  transportation  expenditures:  Unfortunately,  there  is  no  empirical 
evidence  to  indicate  how  federal  expenditures  on  air,  water,  and  rail 
transportation  should  be  allocated  among  income  classes.  It  has  therefore 
been  necessary  to  assume  arbitrarily  that  one-half  of  these  expenditures 
should  be  assigned  to  firms,  and  one-half  to  families.  Again,  it  is  assumed 
that  the  half  attributed  to  firms  is  shifted  forward  to  consumers;  it  is 
thus  allocated,  along  with  the  half  assigned  directly  to  families,  in  pro- 
portion to  expenditures. 

(3)  Educational  expenditures:  While  it  is  recognized  that  the  benefits  of 
education  accrue  widely  to  the  entire  community,  it  has  been  necessary 
in  the  study  to  allocate  all  educational  expenditures  to  those  persons 
being  formally  educated  in  1961.  Indirect  benefits  to  others  are  thus 
ignored.  The  actual  allocation  was  based  on  the  number  of  children  in 
each  income  class  who  were  attending  educational  institutions. 

(4)  Health  and  sanitation:  The  major  expenditure  items  of  this  type  were 
allocated  to  the  different  income  classes  either  on  a  per-capita  basis  or  in 
proportion  to  the  number  of  families  in  each  class.  Where  business  was 
considered  to  be  a  direct  beneficiary,  it  was  assumed  that  the  benefits 
to  business  were  passed  on  to  consumers,  by  means  of  lower  prices. 

(5)  Interest  payments:  Where  possible,  these  were  assigned  to  debt  holders 
in  proportion  to  their  debt  holdings.   Interest  paid  to  business  firms  was 


^The  reasons  underlying  the  selection  of  these  particular  assumptions  are  set  forth  in 
Johnson,  Incidence  of  Government  Revenues  and  Expenditures,  passim. 
*For  details  of  these  allocative  devices,  see  Johnson,  op.  cit. 

169 


Incidence  of  Government  Revenue  and  Expenditure 

assumed  to  benefit  the  owners  of  the  firms,  while  interest  paid  to  insur- 
ance companies  was  assumed  to  be  shifted  forward  to  purchasers  of 
insurance.  Interest  paid  to  government  was  excluded  from  the  analysis, 

(6)  Agricultural  expenditures:  Where  these  expenditures  were  for  purposes 
of  general  administration  and  research,  it  was  assumed  they  were  of  equal 
benefit  to  all  farm  families.  On  the  other  hand,  those  expenditures  associ- 
ated with  marketing  and  production  services,  price  support  programs, 
etc.,  were  assumed  to  benefit  farm  families  in  proportion  to  their  income, 

(7)  Social  welfare  and  expenditures  on  veterans:  It  was  assumed  that  these 
and  other  transfer  payments  were  not  shifted  from  their  initial  recipients, 

(8)  General  government  expenditures:  The  treatment  of  these  was  outlined 
in  the  body  of  the  chapter,  in  paragraph  24.  The  effect  of  the  methods 
we  have  employed  in  allocating  the  benefits  of  general  government 
expenditures  is  that  one-quarter  of  this  total  benefit  is  distributed  equally 
among  individuals,  a  second  quarter  is  distributed  equally  among  families, 
a  third  quarter  is  distributed  among  families  in  proportion  to  their 
incomes,  and  the  remaining  quarter  is  distributed  among  families  in  pro- 
portion to  family  investment  income. 


170 


Chapter 
6 


A  Projection  of  the 
Expenditure,  Revenue  and  Debt 
of  Ontario  Governments,  1966-75 


INTRODUCTION 

1.  By  our  terms  of  reference,  we  were  instructed  to  examine  the  revenue 
systems  of  the  Province  of  Ontario  and  of  its  municipalities,  with  regard  to  both 
present  and  prospective  financial  requirements.  In  response  to  this  latter  charge, 
we  have  developed  projections  of  the  budgetary  and  debt  position  of  the  munici- 
palities and  school  boards  of  Ontario  to  the  end  of  1974  and  of  the  Province  to 
March  31,  1975.  The  results  are  presented  and  explained  in  this  chapter.  We 
shall  first  project  the  revenues  and  expenditures  of  the  municipalities  and  school 
boards  for  each  year  of  the  period,  on  the  basis  of  appropriate  assumptions  which 
are  discussed  below.  The  projected  excess  of  expenditure  over  revenue  indicates 
the  annual  local  deficit  which,  when  added  to  the  debt  at  the  beginning  of  any 
period,  yields  the  total  projected  debt  at  the  end  of  that  year.  We  shall  subsequently 
adopt  a  similar  approach  with  respect  to  the  projection  of  the  revenue,  expenditure 
and  accumulated  debt  of  the  Province.  Finally,  we  shall  present  a  total  of  the 
two  projections,  in  order  to  show  a  comprehensive  picture  for  the  Province  and 
its  subordinate  governments. 

171 


Projection  of  Expenditure,  Revenue  and  Debt 
BASIC  ASSUMPTIONS  OF  THE  PROJECTION 

2.  Because  the  computation  of  these  projections  has  involved  a  large  and 
complex  exercise,  it  is  necessary  at  the  outset  to  make  explicit  the  assumptions  on 
which  they  are  based  and  the  limitations  that  apply  to  them.^  With  respect  to 
revenues,  we  assume  that,  with  two  exceptions,  taxes  will  continue  to  be  collected 
at  rates  prescribed  in  existing  legislation.  The  first  exception  is  the  municipal  real 
property  and  business  taxes  where,  for  reasons  explained  in  a  later  section  of  this 
chapter,  we  have  allowed  for  variations  in  the  rate  of  tax  as  well  as  for  growth 
of  the  tax  base.  The  second  exception,  inasmuch  as  it  may  be  classified  as  a 
tax,  involves  the  premiums  paid  by  individuals  to  the  Ontario  Hospital  Services 
Commission.  We  have  assumed  that  these  premiums  will  be  increased  from  time 
to  time  in  order  that  the  part  of  the  cost  met  by  the  Province  will  not  be  out  of 
line  with  the  one-third  proportion  which  the  Provincial  Treasurer  indicated  as 
being  appropriate,  in  his  1964  Budget  Speech. 

3.  We  have  endeavoured  to  apply  the  same  general  principle  in  our  projection 
of  expenditures,  where  we  have  assumed  that  no  major  changes  in  existing  govern- 
ment policies  will  be  introduced.  The  difficulties  involved  in  projecting  government 
spending  are  nevertheless  substantial,  partly  because  there  are  a  great  many  expen- 
diture programs  whereas  a  large  proportion  of  total  revenue  is  derived  from  a 
very  few  sources.  In  an  attempt  to  establish  an  orderly  classification  of  the  multiple 
categories  of  government  spending  we  have  distinguished  between  current  account 
and  capital  account  spending  for  each  level  of  government.  We  have  further 
divided  each  capital  and  current  expenditure  by  function,  namely  education,  roads 
or  public  works,  health  and  all  other, 

4.  In  each  individual  area  of  expenditure,  our  method  of  making  the  projection 
has  been  adapted  to  the  particular  circumstances,  but  our  usual  procedure  has 
been  (1)  to  consider  the  level  of  spending  on  a  per-capita  basis  at  base  period 
(1963)  prices  and  (2)  to  assume  that  the  trend  of  the  past  few  years  would  con- 
tinue except  where  there  was  definite  reason  to  expect  a  change.  Having  thus 
projected  the  particular  series  in  per-capita  terms  and  at  constant  prices,  we  have 
then  modified  our  figures  to  take  into  account  three  additional  factors:  changes  in 
total  population  or  in  its  relevant  component,  changes  in  the  price  level,  and  an 
"improvement  factor".  If,  for  example,  the  general  level  of  prices  rises,  govern- 
ment expenditure  will  increase  on  that  account.  Likewise,  if  the  size  or  composi- 
tion of  population  to  be  served  changes,  the  total  cost  of  providing  a  given  govern- 
ment program  will  usually  be  directly  affected.  Finally,  we  provide  for  an 
"improvement  factor"  in  the  quality  of  government  services,  because  we  expect 
that  the  average  standard  of  living  of  Ontario  citizens  will  continue  to  rise,  reflect- 
ing rising  standards  of  private  consumption.  As  private  consumption  rises,  the 
level  of  government  services  will  be  expected  to  show  an  accompanying  increase. 


'The  reader  who  is  interested  in  examining  in  greater  detail  the  projections  set  forth  in 
this  chapter  is  referred  to  the  Appendix  following  this  chapter. 


172 


Chapter  6:  Paragraphs  2-8 

We  have  therefore  assumed,  where  relevant,  that  the  appropriate  improvement 
factor  to  apply  to  government  spending  is  equal  to  the  projected  rate  of  increase 
in  productivity  within  the  provincial  economy. 

5.  In  projecting  the  recent  trend  of  any  given  category  of  expenditure  (after 
having  removed  the  statistical  effect  of  any  recent  major  change  in  such  a  spending 
program),  we  have  in  fact  implicitly  assumed  that  the  rate  of  change  in  recent 
expenditure,  which  will  necessarily  reflect  any  minor  modifications  and  extensions 
of  government  spending  programs  introduced  during  the  past  few  years,  will 
continue  in  the  future.  Our  projection,  in  short,  provides  for  the  past  measure  of 
flexibility,  in  adapting  existing  programs  to  changing  conditions.  We  expHcitly 
exclude  from  our  projection  any  provision  for  the  introduction  of  major  new 
expenditures.  We  confidently  expect  that  there  will  in  fact  be  major  new  expen- 
diture programs  introduced  in  the  coming  decade,  but  we  are  in  no  position  to 
predict  what  these  will  be  or  what  they  will  cost.  Our  purpose  here  is  simply  to 
project  from  the  existing  situation,  rather  than  to  forecast  possible  new  develop- 
ments in  the  range  and  scope  of  government  activity. 

6.  To  distinguish  between  a  projection  and  a  forecast  is  also  relevant  in  a 
somewhat  different  sense.  Our  projection  makes  no  attempt  to  take  into  account 
any  short-term  deviations  from  trend,  which  inevitably  occur  in  individual  years. 
Thus,  while  we  shall  offer  the  projected  values  of  the  various  expenditure  and 
revenue  series  in  1969  and  in  1974  (in  the  Appendix  these  values  are  given 
annually  to  1974),  the  value  shown  for  any  one  year  should  be  regarded  more  as 
indicating  the  value  of  the  trend  for  that  year  than  as  a  definite  figure  for  that 
specific  year.  The  values  shown  for  1969,  for  example,  can  more  properly  be 
treated  as  the  projected  average  value  for  the  years  1967-71. 

7.  It  is  clear  from  the  nature  of  our  assumptions  that  the  projections  that 
follow  are  not  intended  to  indicate  what  will  in  fact  be  the  future  fiscal  position 
of  the  provincial  and  municipal  governments  in  Ontario.  Before  our  projections 
could  become  forecasts  of  actual  developments,  they  would  need  to  be  supple- 
mented by  precise  information  concerning  the  details  of  future  economic  events, 
both  in  the  economy  at  large  and  in  the  revenue  and  spending  policies  of  govern- 
ments. The  present  projection  goes  as  far  as  one  can  safely  attempt  to  go  in  any 
ten-year  projection;  to  attempt  to  do  more,  or  to  give  the  impression  that  we  have 
done  more,  would  be  both  dangerous  and  misleading.  But  interpreted  in  the  light 
of  the  assumptions  on  which  they  are  based,  these  projections  take  an  important 
first  step  in  the  assessment  of  the  fiscal  prospects  of  the  governments  with  which 
they  are  concerned. 

PROJECTION  OF  POPULATION,  LABOUR  FORCE,  EMPLOYMENT, 
AND  PROVINCIAL  DOMESTIC  PRODUCT 

8.  Our  projections  of  population,  labour  force,  employment,  and  provincial 
domestic  product  provide  essential  background  for  the  projections  of  the  various 
fiscal  magnitudes  in  which  we  are  primarily  interested.  They  are  also  of  interest 
in  their  own  right.   In  Table  6:1  we  offer  projections  of  some  important  economic 

173 


Projection  of  Expenditure,  Revenue  and  Debt 

variables  for  1969  and  1974,  together  with  actual  figures  for  1963.  The  comments 
following  the  Table  explain  the  bases  of  each  of  the  principal  projections  and  offer 
some  brief  interpretive  observations. 

Table  6:1 

PROJECTED  GROWTH  OF  POPULATION,  LABOUR  FORCE,  EMPLOYMENT, 
AND  PROVINCIAL  DOMESTIC  PRODUCT  FOR  ONTARIO 


1963 


1969 


1974 
as  a 
percentage 
1974  of  1963 


(thousands) 

Population  6,448  7,246  8,054 

Labour    force    2,476  2,805  3,116 

Number  employed  (96%  of  labour  force  in 

1969  and  1974)   2,382  2,693  2,991 

(billions  of  dollars) 

P.D.P.  in  1963  dollars  15.6  19.7  24.2 

P.D.P.  in  current  dollars  15.6  22.2  30.0 


125% 
126 

126 


155 
192 


POPULATION 

9.  The  projection  of  provincial  population  that  we  have  used  was  prepared  by 
the  Ontario  Department  of  Economics  and  Development.  We  have  examined  the 
assumptions  on  which  it  is  based  and  we  consider  them  to  be  reasonable.  The 
projection  assumes  that  there  will  be  a  continuing  decline  in  death  rates,  especially 
for  infants  and  for  persons  over  65  years  of  age.  It  is  further  assumed  that  fertihty 
rates  will  increase  within  the  20-29  age  group  and  remain  unchanged  for  other 
ages.  Net  migration  into  Ontario,  i.e.,  immigration  from  other  provinces  or  from 
other  countries,  less  emigration  to  other  provinces  or  to  other  countries,  is  expected 
to  average  20,000  persons  per  annum. 

1 0.  The  result  of  these  assumptions  is  a  projection  that  shows  an  average  rate 
of  provincial  population  increase  of  2.04  per  cent  per  annum  during  the  period 
1963-74.  This  rate  is  below  that  of  any  of  the  three  quinquennia  of  the  1946-61 
period  but  slightly  above  the  rate  for  the  years  1961-65.  For  the  longer  period, 
1921-65,  the  average  annual  rate  of  increase  was  2.1  per  cent.  Considering  a  still 
longer  period  extending  from  the  census  of  1861  to  1941,  the  rate  of  population 
increase  exceeded  Wa  per  cent  per  annum.  In  the  light  of  this  past  experience 
and  of  current  trends,  the  projected  rate  of  population  growth  of  slightly  more 
than  2  per  cent  a  year  appears  to  be  reasonable. 


LABOUR  FORCE 

1 1 .  From  the  population  projection,  we  derive  the  figures  for  the  expected 
future  labour  force  of  the  province.  In  projecting  the  labour  force,  our  procedure  is 
to  apply  to  each  age  and  sex  group  a  factor  (the  "participation  rate")  for  the 
proportion  of  the  group  that  is  expected  to  be  a  part  of  the  labour  force.    This 

174 


Chapter  6:  Paragraphs  9-16 

yields  the  number  of  persons  from  each  group,  and  the  aggregate  for  all  groups 
gives  the  projected  numbers  in  the  total  provincial  labour  force  in  each  future 
year. 

12.  We  have  assumed,  following  usual  practice,  that  the  labour  force  excludes 
all  persons  less  than  14  years  of  age.  This  means  that  all  members  of  the  1974 
labour  force  were  at  least  two  years  of  age  at  the  beginning  of  1963.  The  major 
element  of  uncertainty  therefore  rests  with  the  labour  force  participation  rates  of 
the  different  age  and  sex  groups. 

13.  For  males,  we  have  assumed  a  fairly  sharp  decline  in  the  proportion  of 
the  14-19  year  age  group  who  will  be  in  the  future  labour  force,  a  more  gradual 
decline  for  those  in  the  20-24  year  group  and  no  change  for  older  age  groups.  For 
females,  our  assumptions  involve  no  net  change  for  those  in  the  14-19  or  20-24 
year  age  groups.  We  expect  that  an  increasing  proportion  of  these  groups  will 
remain  in  full-time  attendance  at  educational  institutions  but  that  of  those  not  so 
engaged,  a  higher  proportion  than  at  present  will  be  in  the  labour  force.  The 
combined  effects  of  these  two  influences  will,  we  anticipate,  produce  no  perceptible 
net  change  in  the  labour  force  participation  rate  for  these  two  female  age  groups. 
For  females  aged  25  and  over  we  have  assumed,  for  all  age  groups,  a  continuous 
increase  in  the  participation  rate,  for  the  duration  of  our  forecast  period. 

PROVINCIAL  DOMESTIC  PRODUCT 

14.  "Provincial  gross  domestic  product  at  factor  cost"  (hereafter  designated 
P.D.P.)  is  a  measure  of  the  total  value  of  goods  and  services  produced,  and  hence  of 
the  total  income  generated,  within  the  geographical  boundaries  of  the  Province  of 
Ontario  during  a  given  interval  of  time,  usually  one  year.  The  figure  is  arrived  at 
before  any  deduction  for  depreciation  and  before  the  addition  of  that  part  of  value 
represented  by  indirect  taxes.  The  P.D.P.  is  projected  as  the  product  of  two 
factors — the  average  number  of  employed  persons  and  the  average  P.D.P.  per 
person  employed. 

15.  We  have  already  described  the  labour  force  projection  which,  after  allow- 
ance for  unemployment,  indicates  the  average  number  employed  in  each  year  of 
the  period.  In  the  years  since  the  inflation  that  accompanied  the  Korean  War,  the 
unemployment  figure  for  Ontario  has  averaged  about  4  per  cent  of  the  provincial 
labour  force.  After  carefully  examining  the  historical  record  and  evaluating  recent 
trends,  we  are  projecting  average  annual  unemployment  at  this  4  per  cent  level  of 
the  labour  force.  The  employed  labour  force  is  thus  expected  to  average  96  per 
cent  of  the  total  labour  force  and,  since  we  have  already  projected  the  total  labour 
force,  it  is  a  simple  matter  to  calculate  the  projected  number  of  persons  employed, 
in  each  of  the  years  with  which  we  are  concerned, 

16.  The  other  element  in  this  projection  is  the  average  contribution  to  P.D.P. 
per  person  employed.  This  figure  was  just  under  $6,500  in  1963  and  we  have 
projected  its  increase  at  2  per  cent  per  annum  in  real  terms,  i.e.,  at  constant 

175 


Projection  of  Expenditure,  Revenue  and  Debt 

prices.  This  rate  of  increase  approximates  the  average  of  the  past  twelve  years 
and  in  so  far  as  one  can  judge  from  the  evidence  available,  it  is  also  very  close  to 
the  long-term  average  rate  of  increase  in  productivity  within  the  provincial 
economy. 

17.  At  this  point  we  have  now  developed  all  the  constituents  required  to 
project  the  P.D.P.  in  constant  dollars.  We  are  concerned,  however,  with  the  actual 
amount  of  government  revenue  and  government  expenditure  in  the  current  dollars 
of  the  respective  future  years.  This  means  that  we  must  also  consider  future 
changes  in  the  level  of  prices.  In  making  our  assessment  of  the  future  trend  of 
the  general  price  level,  we  have  examined  the  record  since  1952  and  considered  the 
forces  that  seem  likely  to  operate  in  the  future.  Our  conclusion  is  that  our  pro- 
jection should  allow  for  a  general  price  increase  of  2  per  cent  per  annum  and  our 
current-dollar  projection  of  P.D.P.  has  been  calculated  accordingly. 

18.  Our  projected  P.D.P.  in  current  dollars  rises  from  $15.6  billion  in  1963 
to  $30.0  billion  in  1974.  This  increase  of  92  per  cent  in  eleven  years  represents  an 
average  increase  of  6.1  per  cent  per  annum.  For  each  individual  year,  the  increase 
over  the  preceding  year  is  in  no  instance  far  from  this  average.  Of  this  total  of 
6.1  per  cent,  price  increase  accounts  for  2  per  cent,  so  that  the  increase  in  pro- 
duction in  real  terms  averages  some  4.1  per  cent  a  year.  This  annual  4.1  per  cent 
increase  in  physical  volume  is,  in  turn,  made  up  of  a  2  per  cent  increase  in  per- 
capita  productivity  and  an  average  increase  of  just  under  2.1  per  cent  in  the 
number  of  persons  employed. 

19.  Beginning  with  1963  as  the  base  year,  the  average  projected  rate  of 
increase  in  P.D.P.  is  in  every  year  close  to  6  per  cent.  We  note  that  the  actual 
P.D.P.  in  1964  and  1965  was  somewhat  above  our  figures  projected  for  these 
years  and  it  likewise  seems  certain  that  in  1966  the  realized  P.D.P.  will  again  exceed 
our  projected  figure.  The  years  since  1963  have,  however,  shown  a  higher  average 
level  of  prosperity,  and  so  a  more  rapid  rate  of  increase  in  income,  than  we  would 
expect  on  the  average  over  a  decade.  Just  as  P.D.P.  has  grown  more  rapidly  than 
we  have  projected  in  the  years  since  1963,  so  it  is  probable  that  in  some  future 
years  it  will  grow  less  rapidly.  Consequently,  we  have  not  revised  the  figures  in 
our  projection  for  1969  or  later  years.  Our  procedure  has  been  to  replace  our 
projected  P.D.P.  for  1964,  1965  and  1966  with  either  the  actual  figure  or  the  best 
estimate  for  each  of  these  years.  We  assume  that  in  the  years  immediately  after 
1966  the  rate  of  growth  will  be  such  that  by  1969  the  actual  P.D.P.  will  coincide 
with  our  projected  figure.  We  therefore  assume  that  beginning  with  1969,  the 
P.D.P.  figures  in  our  projection  are  the  appropriate  ones  to  use. 

20.  These  projections  of  provincial  population,  labour  force,  and  product 
represent  the  indispensable  background  for  the  projection  of  the  required  fiscal 
magnitudes  of  the  provincial  and  local  governments  in  Ontario.  It  is  to  a  considera- 
tion of  these  magnitudes  that  we  must  now  direct  our  attention. 

176 


Chapter  6:  Paragraphs  17-24 

PROJECTION  OF  MUNICIPAL  AND  SCHOOL  BOARD  REVENUE, 
EXPENDITURE  AND  DEBT 

2 1 .  In  our  projections  of  the  budgetary  position  of  each  level  of  government,  we 
shall  begin  with  revenues,  follow  with  expenditures  and  then  consider  inter- 
governmental transfers.  Finally,  in  bringing  together  all  of  these  series,  we  shall  be 
able  to  show  the  projected  cumulative  total  of  government  debt.  We  shall  first 
consider  the  fiscal  position  of  the  municipalities  and  school  boards,  and  then  turn 
our  attention  to  that  of  the  provincial  government. 

MUNICIPAL  REVENUES 

22.  The  real  property  and  business  taxes  are  by  far  the  most  important  source 
of  rnunicipal  net  revenue,  accounting  for  some  90  per  cent  of  the  total.  The  other 
sources  are  federal  and  provincial  grants  in  lieu  of  such  property  taxes,  and 
miscellaneous  revenues  from  permits,  fees,  licences,  fines,  etc. 

Table  6:2 

MUNICIPAL  REVENUES 

(Excluding  grants  from  Province) 


Property  and  business  taxes  

Federal  subsidies,  and  grants  in  lieu  of  taxes 
Other  current  revenues  

Total   Revenue   

P.D.P 

Total  Revenue  as  percentage  of  P.D.P 


1974 

as  a 

percentage 

1963 

7969 

1974 

of  1963 

(millions  of  dollars) 

lAA 

1,186 

1,748 

235% 

18 

26 

34 

189 

68 

91 

125 
1,907 

184 

830 

1,303 

230 

15,600 

22,200 

30,000 

192 

5.3% 

5.9% 

6.4% 

23.  The  figures  in  Table  6:2  show  the  major  items  of  municipal  revenue,  the 
relative  increase  in  each  over  the  period  1963  to  1974,  and  the  relationship  of 
total  municipal  revenue  to  P.D.P.  in  each  indicated  year.  Detailed  comment  is 
required  only  in  explaining  our  basis  of  projecting  the  revenue  from  the  property 
and  business  taxes. 

24,  For  all  taxes  except  the  property  and  business  taxes,  we  have  assumed  a 
constant  tax  rate  and  we  have  projected  the  yield  of  each  tax  at  the  appropriate  rate. 
For  the  property  and  business  taxes,  there  are  both  economic  and  legal  grounds 
for  projecting  the  yield  on  the  basis  of  variable  tax  rates.  The  economic  reason 
derives  from  the  fact  that  for  all  or  nearly  all  of  the  other  taxes — e.g.  the  personal 
income  tax,  the  sales  tax  and  the  corporation  income  tax — a  rise  in  the  price  level 
will  bring,  directly  or  indirectly,  an  increase  in  the  tax  base.  An  increase  in 
revenue  is  thereby  realized  without  any  increase  in  the  tax  rate.  Here  the  elasticity 
of  the  tax  yield  is  provided  through  the  tax  base  and  there  is  consequently  less 
need  for  variation  in  the  tax  rate.  For  the  municipal  real  property  tax,  adjustments 

177 


Projection  of  Expenditure,  Revenue  and  Debt 

in  the  tax  base  (the  assessed  value  of  a  given  piece  of  property)  tend  to  lag  far 
behind  rising  property  values  and  the  continuously  increasing  costs  of  municipal 
government.  Elsewhere  in  our  Report  we  recommend  a  transition  to  the  assess- 
ment of  real  property  at  current  market  value,  a  procedure  that  would  greatly 
lessen  the  present  rigidities  in  the  municipal  tax  base.  Given  prevalent  assessment 
procedures,  the  chief  element  of  elasticity  in  the  real  property  tax  base  tends  to 
come  from  new  capital  construction  which,  of  course,  provides  an  increase  in 
total  assessment.  In  the  past,  such  new  construction  has  not  provided  a  sufficient 
degree  of  elasticity  to  overcome  the  relative  inflexibility  in  the  tax  base,  and  this 
has  necessitated  year-to-year  increases  in  the  tax  rate. 

25.  The  legislative  procedure  for  striking  real  property  tax  rates  further 
strengthens  the  case  for  projecting  a  variable  rate  of  tax.  If  we  consider  other 
taxes,  we  find  that  once  the  rate  has  been  set,  it  tends  to  remain  for  some  time  at 
the  level  specified,  until  changed  by  new  legislation.  By  contrast,  the  municipal 
property  tax  rate  is  set  for  one  year  only  and  it  is  struck  anew  each  year.  We  think 
that  our  projection  procedure  should  reflect  this  fact,  and  we  have  accordingly 
projected  a  change  in  the  rate  of  tax.  In  1963,  the  average  rate  of  the  tax  was 
65  mills  per  dollar  of  assessment,  and  for  some  time  prior  to  1963  the  rate  has 
been  increasing  by  an  average  IVi  per  cent  per  year.  We  therefore  projected  at 
this  same  rate  a  continued  upward  movement  in  the  average  yield  of  the  tax  per 
dollar  of  taxable  assessment.  The  result  is  that  by  1974  the  rate  will  reach  76 
mills.   This  increase  is,  of  course,  reflected  in  the  figures  shown  in  Table  6:2. 

26.  It  may  be  thought  that  the  projected  increase  in  the  real  property  tax  rate 
is  unduly  great  and  that  the  upward  trend  of  the  past  few  years  cannot  continue 
as  rapidly  in  the  coming  decade.  An  examination  of  the  historical  record  shows, 
however,  that  the  yield  of  this  tax  in  relation  to  P.D.P.  was  unusuafly  low  just 
after  the  war  and  that  even  after  the  increases  of  the  past  fifteen  years,  its  yield 
was  still  a  smaller  proportion  of  P.D.P.  than  it  was  in  the  late  1920's.  In  1926,  for 
example,  the  yield  was  5.4  per  cent  of  P.D.P.,  in  1929  5.0  per  cent  and  in  1939 
it  was  again  5.4  per  cent.  In  1963,  the  comparable  figure  was  4.8  per  cent,  and 
by  1974,  according  to  our  projection,  it  will  have  risen  to  only  5.8  per  cent,  which 
is  no  higher  than  it  was  in  1937.  Most  taxes  today  take  a  higher  proportion  of 
income  than  they  did  in  the  inter-war  period.  In  view  of  this  fact,  and  the  fact  that 
municipalities  are  now  expected  to  provide  a  much  higher  standard  of  services, 
especially  in  the  costly  areas  of  education,  roads,  and  social  welfare,  the  projected 
yield  of  the  municipal  property  tax  appears  to  be  consistent  with  historical 
experience. 

27.  Federal  contributions,  grants  and  subsidies  to  municipalities  in  Ontario 
totalled  $18  million  in  1963,  of  which  the  major  item,  was  grants  in  lieu  of  taxes 
on  federal  property,  which  is  legally  exempt  from  taxation  by  the  local  governments 
in  the  various  municipalities.  All  other  municipal  current  revenues  in  1963 
amounted  to  $68  million.  These  two  groups  of  revenues  were  projected  separately, 
but  each  projection  assumes  the  continuation  of  past  trends. 

178 


Chapter  6:  Paragraphs  25-30 

SCHOOL  BOARD  EXPENDITURE 

28.  In  our  projection  of  school  board  expenditures  we  have  considered 
separately  expenditures  for  elementary  and  for  secondary  education,  and  at  each 
level  we  have  distinguished  between  current  and  capital  expenditures.  The  cost  of 
servicing  debt  incurred  for  educational  purposes  has  been  included  in  the  total 
for  local  government  debt  service  shown  in  Table  6:6. 

29.  Our  consideration  of  education  costs  begins  with  a  projection  of  the 
number  of  pupils  expected  to  occupy  places  in  the  schools.  We  assume  that  the 
average  number  of  pupils  per  teacher  will  decline  gradually,  at  both  the  elementary 
and,  somewhat  more  rapidly,  the  secondary  level,  and  that  teachers'  average 
salaries  will  increase  at  the  rate  of  3Vi  per  cent  per  annum  for  public  school 
teachers  and  4  per  cent  per  annum  for  high  school  teachers.  Continuing  the  trend 
of  recent  years,  our  projection  provides  for  an  increasing  proportion  of  elementary 
school  pupils  to  be  enrolled  in  separate  schools  and  for  a  further  narrowing  of  the 
spread  between  the  average  cost  per  pupil  in  public  and  in  separate  elementary 
schools.  The  combined  effect  of  all  these  factors  leads  to  a  projected  increase  in 
average  cost  of  5V2  per  cent  per  annum  per  pupil  enrolled  (considering  public  and 
separate  elementary  school  pupils  in  total).  For  secondary  school  students,  the 
comparable  figure  is  just  under  6  per  cent. 

30.  Our  projection  of  capital  expenditure  provides  for  the  addition  of  new 
school-places  to  accommodate  anticipated  increased  enrolments  and  for  the 
replacement  by  1975  of  almost  all  school  accommodation  built  before  1945.  We 

Table  6:3 
EXPENDITURE   BY   ELEMENTARY  AND   SECONDARY   SCHOOL   BOARDS 

7974 
as  a 
percentage 
1963  1969         1974      of  1963 


Elementary  School  Boards 

Number  of  pupils   (thousands)    1,233         1,406         1.537         125% 

Current  operating  cost   (millions)    $295  $464       $    662         224 

Capital  outlays  for  new  places  and  replacement 

of   existing   places    (millions)    41  57  77  188 

Total   Elementary   Expenditure    $336  $521       $    739         220 

Secondary  School  Boards 

Number  of  pupils   (thousands)    364  507  577         159 

Current  operating  cost   (millions)    $180  $365       $    535         297 

Capital  outlays  for  new  places  and  replacement 

of  existing  places   (millions)    17*  38  51         300 

Total  Secondary  Expenditure  $197  $403       $    586         297 

Total  School   Board   Expenditure   $533  $924       $1.325         249 

Total  School  Board  Expenditure  as  a  percentage  of 

P.D.P 3.4%         4.2%         4.4% 

*This  figure  does  not  include  grants  received  for  the  construction  of  vocational  schools. 

179 


Projection  of  Expenditure,  Revenue  and  Debt 

have  also  provided,  in  our  projection  of  capital  costs,  for  an  annual  increase  of  2 
per  cent  in  the  general  price  level  and  for  an  additional  annual  increase  of  2  per 
cent  for  improvements  in  the  quality  of  school  facilities. 

MUNICIPAL  EXPENDITURE 

31.  In  projecting  this  category  of  expenditures  we  have,  as  with  education, 
considered  current  and  capital  spending  separately.  As  components  of  current 
expenditure,  we  have  made  separate  projections  for  public  works  and  for  health. 
Interest  payments  are  not  included  here,  inasmuch  as  they  cannot  be  calculated 
until  we  have  projected  a  figure  for  the  amount  of  debt  outstanding  at  the  beginning 
of  each  year,  as  shown  in  Table  6:6.  "All  other"  current  expenditures  have  been 
projected  as  a  single  aggregate. 

32.  Municipal  expenditures  on  capital  account  have  been  projected  under  the 
major  categories  of  public  works,  sanitation,  health  and  other.  The  capital  expen- 
diture figures  in  Table  6:4  include  only  those  incurred  in  acquiring  durable  real 
assets  and  exclude  outlays  for  debt  retirement.  Such  debt  retirement  outlays  have 
in  recent  years  amounted  to  some  18  per  cent  of  total  municipal  capital  expendi- 
ture.- 

Table6:4 
MUNICIPAL  CURRENT  AND  CAPITAL  EXPENDITURE* 

1974 
as  a 
percentage 
1963  1969         1974       of  1963 

(millions  of  dollars) 
Current  Expenditure 

Public    works    133  200  264         198% 

Health    17  30  47         276 

Other    341  515  733         215 

Total  Current  Expenditure  491  745         1,044         213 

Capital  Expenditure 

Public  works  134  226  322  240 

Sanitation     57  98  153  268 

Health    5  16  25  500 

Other   28  53  73  261 

Total  Capital   Expenditure   224  393  573         256 

Total  Municipal  Expenditure  715         1,138         1,617         226 

Total  Municipal  Expenditure  as  percentage  of  P. D.P.  4.6%         5.1%         5.4% 

'Expenditures  for  education  and  for  interest  on  debt  are  not  included  in  this  Table.  For 
information  on  these  items,  see  Table  6:3  and  Table  6:6. 

33.  The  projected  expenditures  on  public  works,  both  on  current  and  on 
capital  account,  have  been  derived  from  the  provincial  grants  made  to  municipalities 
for  roads,  streets,  etc.  The  method  of  projecting  these  provincial  grants  is  described 


"Dominion  Bureau  of  Statistics,  Financial  Statistics  of  Municipal  Governments. 

180 


Chapter  6:  Paragraphs  31-38 

in  a  later  section  of  this  chapter.  We  have  assumed  that  the  proportion  of  the 
total  municipal  expenditure  covered  by  these  grants  will  remain  at  approximately 
the  average  level  of  the  past  few  years  and  we  have  derived  total  expenditure  on 
current  and  capital  accounts  respectively  from  the  projected  provincial  grants  for 
these  categories  of  expenditure. 

34.  Capital  outlays  on  sanitation  have  been  a  major  item  of  municipal  expendi- 
ture throughout  the  past  decade.  After  examining  these  outlays  between  1953  and 
1964,  we  concluded  that  we  should  allow  for  an  increase  in  sanitation  expenditures 
at  the  rate  of  5  per  cent  per  annum  per  capita,  in  constant  dollars.  When  the 
constant  dollar  figures  are  converted  to  a  current  basis  and  then  multiplied  by  the 
pop'ulation,  we  arrive  at  the  projected  expenditure  figure. 

35.  Municipal  expenditures  on  health,  whether  on  current  or  capital  account, 
are  small  in  relation  to  total  municipal  expenditures.  Changes  now  taking  place 
in  this  field  make  it  very  difficult  to  establish  a  firm  basis  on  which  to  make  a 
projection,  but  we  expect  that  there  will  be  a  continuing  increase  in  the  scope  and 
cost  of  various  kinds  of  public  health  measures.  We  have  allowed  in  our  projection 
for  an  average  increase  in  current  health  expenditure  of  $3  million  per  annum  and 
for  an  average  increase  of  $2  million  per  annum  in  capital  outlays.  In  percentage 
terms,  this  involves  a  rapid  rate  of  increase,  but  the  projected  total  municipal  ex- 
penditure on  health,  current  and  capital  combined,  will  be  less  than  5  per  cent  of 
total  municipal  expenditure  in  every  year  of  the  period. 

36.  For  "all  other"  expenditure,  both  current  and  capital,  the  general  technique 
used  is  similar  to  that  used  for  sanitation.  In  these  areas,  however,  the  projected 
rate  of  increase  is  between  3V^  and  4  per  cent  per  annum  per  capita  in  constant 
dollars,  and  this  expenditure  therefore  increases  at  7  to  8  per  cent  per  annum  in 
current  dollars. 

GRANTS  TO  LOCAL  GOVERNMENTS  FROM  THE  PROVINCE 

37.  Local  governments  receive  grants  from  the  Province  for  many  different 
purposes,  but  in  recent  years  some  70  to  75  per  cent  of  the  total  dollar  amount 
of  such  grants  has  been  directed  to  education  and  to  public  works,  mainly  streets 
and  roads.  Other  substantial  but  smaller  amounts  have  been  paid  to  the  municipali- 
ties for  general  welfare  assistance  and  as  unconditional  grants. 

38.  The  introduction  of  the  Ontario  Foundation  Tax  Plan  in  1964  raised  the 
level  of  provincial  government  support  for  elementary  and  secondary  school  boards. 
In  1966  it  is  estimated  that  provincial  grants  will  cover  48  per  cent  of  school  board 
expenditures  for  current  operations,  capital  expenditure  financed  from  current 
revenues,  and  debt  service  costs.  We  have  assumed  that  with  the  continuing  growth 
of  these  school  board  expenditures,  the  relative  size  of  provincial  grants  will 
decline  by  1  percentage  point  a  year,  although  the  absolute  amount  will  increase 
very  substantially,  until  it  reaches  45  per  cent  in  1969;  thereafter,  this  percentage 
is  assumed  to  be  maintained  until  the  end  of  our  forecast  period. 

181 


Projection  of  Expenditure,  Revenue  and  Debt 

39.  The  Province  also  makes  large  grants  to  the  municipalities  for  roads  and 
streets.  These  grants  now  amount  to  about  one-third  of  total  municipal  expenditure 
on  highways,  roads  and  streets,  and  we  have  assumed  that  there  will  be  no  significant 
change  in  this  proportion.  Total  expenditure  on  these  items  by  the  Province  has 
been  projected  in  the  provincial  section  of  this  chapter,  and  we  have  used  the  data 
from  that  section  in  projecting  these  grants  to  the  municipalities.  Of  the  total  of 
such  grants,  we  have  assumed  that  approximately  two-thirds  would  be  for  capitzil 
projects  and  one-third  for  expenditures  on  current  account.  However,  if  the  pro- 
jection is  examined  in  more  detail,  it  will  be  seen  that  we  have  allowed  for  a  some- 
what more  rapid  growth  of  grants  related  to  capital  expenditure  than  for  those 
related  to  expenditure  on  current  account,  i.e.,  repair  and  maintenance  of  roads 
and  streets. 

40.  For  our  present  purposes,  we  have  grouped  in  a  single  category  all  other 
provincial  grants  to  the  municipalities.  In  1965  and  1966,  these  grants  averaged 
18  per  cent  of  estimated  municipal  expenditure,  apart  from  outlays  for  education 
and  roads.  This  percentage  has  shown  a  persistent  upward  trend  over  the  past 
decade,  but  this  reflects  mainly  changes  in  the  bases  on  which  such  grants  have 
been  made.  For  purposes  of  this  projection,  we  are  assuming  that  the  present 
bases  of  making  the  grants  will  not  change  and  we  have  therefore  projected  the 
amount  of  the  grants  throughout  the  period  at  the  18  per  cent  figure  that  represents 
the  1965  and  1966  average.  We  have  assumed,  from  the  experience  of  recent 
years,  that  80  per  cent  of  these  grants  will  apply  to  current  expenditure  and  20 
per  cent  to  capital  expenditure. 

Table  6:5 
LOCAL  GOVERNMENT  GRANTS  RECEIVED  FROM  THE  PROVINCE 


Current  Account  Grants 

Education    

Public    works    

Other  current   

Total  Current  Grants   

Capital  and  Debt  Service  Grants 

Education    

Public  works  

Other   capital    

Total   Capital   Grants   

Total  Grants   

Total    Grants    as    percentage    of    Total    Local 

Expenditure     29%  33%  33% 

182 


1974 

as  a 

percentage 

1963 

1969        1974 

of  1963 

(millions  of  dollars) 

193 

388     560 

290% 

32 

46      61 

191 

58 

102     149 

257 

283 

536     770 

272 

36 

61      84 

233 

53 

89     124 

234 

14 

26      37 

264 

103 

176     245 

238 

386 

712    1,015 

263 

Chapter  6:  Paragraphs  39-42 

budgetary  and  debt  position 

41.  We  now  bring  together  in  Table  6:6  the  projected  totals  for  the  various 
items  of  local  revenue,  grants  and  expenditure,  in  order  to  provide  a  general 
picture  of  the  over-all  financial  position  of  the  municipalities  and  school  boards. 

Table  6:6 
BUDGETARY  AND  DEBT  POSITION  OF  LOCAL  GOVERNMENTS 

1974 
as  a 
percentage 
1963  1969         1974       of  1963 


(millions  of  dollars) 
Revenue 

\.            Local  government  current  revenues  830  1,303  1,907  230% 

2.  Grants  from  Province  for  current  purposes  283  536  770  272 

3.  Total  Revenue  on  Current  Account  1,113  1,839  2,677  241 

Current  Expenditure 

4.  Expenditures  on  current  account  (exclud- 

ing interest)  966  1,574  2,241  232 

5.  Interest    65  110  154  237 

6.  Total  Expenditure  on  Current  Account  ..  1,031  1,684  2,395  232 

7.  Surplus  on  Current  Account  82  155  282  344 

Capital  Expenditure 

8.  Expenditures  on  capital  account  282  488  701  249 

9.  Less  provincial  grants  for  capital  purposes  103  176  245  238 

10.  Capital  Expenditure  Net  of  Grants  179  312  456  255 

11.  Deficit  (=  increase  in  debt)   97  157  174  179 

12.  Net  debt  outstanding  (December  31)   1,499  2,380  3,244  216 

13.  Estimated  separate  school  net  debt  133  190  247  186 

14.  Net  debt  outstanding    (excluding  separate 

school  net  debt)   1,366  2,190  2^97  219 

15.  Provincial  Domestic  Product  15,600  22,200  30,000  192 

16.  Debt  (line  14)  as  Percentage  of  P.D.P 8.8%  9.9%  10.0% 


42.  The  figures  in  Table  6:6  are  so  arranged  as  to  show  total  revenue,  includ- 
ing grants,  on  current  account,  total  current  account  expenditure  and,  in  line  7  of 
the  Table,  the  surplus  on  current  account,  after  providing  for  interest  on  debt  but 
before  providing  for  any  capital  repayments  or  for  the  financing  of  any  capital 
expenditure  from  current  revenue.  Total  capital  expenditure  less  grants  on  capital 
account  is  shown  in  line  10  and  the  figure  for  the  increase  in  debt — i.e.,  the  excess 
of  total  expenditure  over  total  revenue — appears  in  line  1 1 .  This  annual  increase 
in  debt,  when  added  to  the  figure  at  the  beginning  of  the  year,  gives  in  line  12 
the  total  net  debt  outstanding  at  the  end  of  the  year.  This  total  comprises  general 
municipal  and  school  board  debt  but  excludes  the  debt  of  municipal  utilities,  which 
is  deemed  to  be  self-liquidating.  Separate  school  debt  is  included  in  the  figures 
shown  in  line  12,  but  because  this  is  not  a  municipal  liability,  this  debt  (net  of 

183 


Projection  of  Expenditure,  Revenue  and  Debt 

sinking  funds)  has  been  deducted,  to  give  the  relevant  measure  of  the  net  debt  of 
local  governments,  Hne  14.  The  bottom  section  of  the  Table  shows  the  net  debt 
in  each  of  three  years  as  a  percentage  of  P.D.P.  in  that  year. 

43.  It  will  be  noted  that  in  each  of  these  years  (and  it  is  true  for  all  the  other 
years  of  the  period  as  well)  a  surplus  on  current  account  transactions  is  projected. 
However,  after  taking  expenditure  for  capital  purposes  into  account,  there  is  a 
continuous  increase  in  the  net  debt.  This  increase,  if  we  include  the  debt  of 
separate-school  boards,  was  $97  million  in  1963  and  is  projected  to  rise  to  $157 
million  in  1969  and  to  $174  million  in  1974.  If  the  increase  in  separate  school 
debt  is  excluded,  the  comparable  figures  are  $87,  $147  and  $161  million. 

44.  The  cumulative  effect  of  these  annual  increases  is  to  raise  local  net  debt, 
excluding  that  of  separate  school  boards,  by  about  60  per  cent  between  1963  and 
1969,  and  in  the  remaining  five  years  of  our  projection  period  a  further  increase  of 
some  35  per  cent  occurs.  By  the  end  of  1974  the  debt  total  is  therefore  about  two 
and  one-quarter  times  that  of  1963.  In  relation  to  P.D.P.,  the  debt  rises  fairly 
rapidly  from  8.8  per  cent  in  1963  to  9.9  per  cent  in  1969  but  after  1969  there  is 
virtually  no  change  in  the  ratio  of  debt  to  P.D.P.  in  any  of  the  remaining  years. 

45.  Let  us  now  review  this  projected  debt  of  Ontario's  local  governments  in 
the  light  of  historical  experience.  Data  are  not  available  for  the  1920's,  but  in 
1939  local  government  debt  in  the  province  was  an  estimated  11  per  cent  of 
P.D.P.  By  1955  it  had  declined  to  5  per  cent,  but  since  that  time  it  has  been 
rising.  Our  projection  indicates  that  this  increase  will  continue  until  1970,  after 
which  time  the  ratio  of  debt  to  P.D.P.  will  remain  constant,  at  a  figure  slightly 
below  that  for  1939.  We  should  nevertheless  remind  ourselves  once  again  of  the 
assumptions  on  which  this  conclusion  is  based.  We  have  assumed  a  continuation 
of  the  past  rate  of  increase  in  the  mill  rate  of  the  real  property  and  business  tax, 
but  apart  from  this  we  have  projected  other  revenues  and  grants  on  their  present 
basis.  On  the  expenditure  side,  the  projected  costs  of  municipal  and  school  board 
services  take  account  of  constantly  improving  quality,  a  growing  population  and  a 
rising  trend  in  the  general  price  level.  In  addition,  by  projecting  past  trends,  we 
have  built  in  some  provision  for  continuing  modifications  and  extensions  of  exist- 
ing programs  and  for  the  addition  of  minor  new  programs,  at  the  same  rate  as  in 
recent  years. 

46.  In  summary,  we  conclude  that  with  a  rise  in  net  municipal  and  school 
board  debt  to  a  level  slightly  above  its  present  proportion  of  P.D.P.,  but  to  less 
than  that  of  the  late  1930's,  the  present  local  revenue  system  will  generate  sufficient 
financial  resources  to  permit  Ontario  municipalities  and  school  boards  to  discharge 
their  responsibilities  satisfactorily,  in  the  absence  of  any  large  new  programs.  This 
is  not  to  suggest,  however,  that  the  local  revenue  system  may  be  regarded  as  either 
adequate  or  equitable,  and  many  of  the  subsequent  recommendations  in  our  Report 
are  designed  to  improve  the  system  in  these  respects. 

184 


Chapter  6:  Paragraphs  43-51 
PROJECTIONS  OF  PROVINCIAL  REVENUE 

47.  In  projecting  the  fiscal  position  of  the  Province,  we  shall  proceed  along 
lines  similar  to  those  adopted  in  dealing  with  the  municipalities  and  school  boards. 
We  shall  begin  with  a  projection  of  revenues  and  then  go  on  to  consider  expendi- 
tures, classified  as  to  current  account  and  capital  account.  Transfers  from  the 
Province  to  the  municipahties  and  school  boards  are  considered  next,  and  finally 
we  bring  together  the  total  revenue  and  total  expenditure  figures.  We  thereby 
arrive  at  the  projected  surplus  or  deficit  position  of  the  Province  for  each  year,  as 
well  as  the  accumulated  provincial  debt  at  the  end  of  each  year  of  the  projection 
period. 

48.  The  aggregate  which  we  first  project  is  the  total  revenue  on  current  account 
or,  to  use  the  ofl&cial  terminology,  the  total  "net  ordinary  revenue"  of  the  Province. 
In  recent  years,  approximately  90  per  cent  of  this  revenue  has  come  from  eight 
revenue  sources,  the  remaining  10  per  cent  being  derived  from  a  multitude  of 
miscellaneous  forms  of  income.  Our  procedure  will  be  to  project  separately  the 
revenue  yield  of  each  of  the  eight  major  sources  and  to  deal  with  all  other  sources 
as  a  single  item.  All  projections  assume  that  the  provincial  tax  rates  and  the 
general  revenue  structure  remain,  throughout  the  period,  as  they  were  after  the 
1966  provincial  budget  changes  were  effected. 

49.  In  each  of  four  major  sources  of  revenue,  it  was  found  that  revenue  in 
recent  years  has  shown  little  variation  when  expressed  as  a  percentage  of  P.D.P. 
We  therefore  projected  the  yield  from  each  of  these  sources,  at  1966  tax  levels, 
as  a  simple  percentage  of  P.D.P.  The  revenue  items  involved,  and  the  percentages 
used  for  each,  are  shown  below. 

Percentage 
Revenue  Source  of  P.D.P. 

Corporations  Tax  1.35% 

Retail  Sales  Tax  1.95 

Succession  Duty  0.285 

Liquor  Control  Board  0.67 

SHARE  OF  FEDERAL  ESTATE  TAX 

50.  In  addition,  the  Province's  share  of  revenue  from  the  federal  estate  tax  was 
projected  as  one-third  of  the  revenue  from  succession  duty,  so  that  the  projected 
revenue  from  this  fifth  source  depends  ultimately  on  the  size  of  the  P.D.P. 

GASOLINE  TAX 

51.  The  Ontario  gasoline  tax  was  raised  to  16  cents  per  gallon  in  the  1966 
Budget.  Because  it  is  based  on  the  physical  quantity  of  gasoline  subject  to  tax, 
the  yield  might  be  expected  to  be  related  to  P.D.P.  at  constant  prices,  which  is  to 
say,  to  the  physical  volume  of  production  of  goods  and  services.  In  fact,  the  yield 
of  the  gasoline  tax  in  recent  years,  after  adjustment  for  changes  in  the  rate,  has 
been  a  very  nearly  constant  proportion  of  P.D.P.  when  this  latter  magnitude  is 

185 


Projection  of  Expenditure,  Revenue  and  Debt 

valued  at  constant  prices.  The  future  yield  of  the  tax  has  therefore  been  projected 
at  1.40  per  cent  of  P.D.P.,  valued  at  1963  prices, 

MOTOR  VEHICLE  LICENCES  AND  PERMITS 

52.  There  are  several  items  in  this  group,  of  which  licences  for  passenger  and 
commercial  vehicles  provide  the  bulk  of  the  revenue.  For  passenger  licences,  our 
procedure  has  been  to  calculate  the  average  licence  fee  per  vehicle,  to  project  the 
number  of  vehicles,  using  an  equation  involving  the  historical  relationship  between 
the  number  of  licensed  passenger  vehicles  and  the  population,  and  thereby  to  de- 
rive the  total  projected  revenue.  A  similar  procedure  has  been  used  in  projecting 
commercial  vehicle  Ucence  revenues.  Other  revenues  in  this  group,  which  are 
small  and  have  been  growing  slowly,  were  projected  by  a  simple  extrapolation  of 
their  past  trend. 

PERSONAL  INCOME  TAX 

53.  Here  we  have  projected  the  total  personal  income  tax  to  be  collected  from 
residents  of  Ontario  by  the  federal  government  on  its  own  behalf  and  on  behalf  of 
the  Province.  The  description  of  this  projection  is  complex  but  a  brief  outline 
will  be  found  in  the  Appendix.  For  1966  and  subsequent  years,  it  was  assumed 
that  24  per  cent  of  the  relevant  amount  of  tax  collected  would  be  paid  to  Ontario, 
in  accordance  with  the  terms  of  the  Province's  then  current  taxation  agree- 
ment   with   the   federal    government. 

Table  6:7 

REVENUES  OF  THE  GOVERNMENT  OF  ONTARIO— FISCAL  YEARS  ENDING 

MARCH  31" 

7975 
as  a 
percentage 
1964         1970        1975      of  1964 


(millions  of  dollars) 

Personal  income  tax  164  428  635  387% 

Corporations  tax 210  300  405  193 

Gasoline  tax  184  276  337  183 

Retail  sales  tax   187  433  585  313 

Succession  duty  44  63  86  195 

Motor  vehicle  permits,  etc 76  94  113  149 

Liquor  Control  Board  of  Ontario  97  149  201  207 

Share  of  federal  estate  tax  —  21  29  — 

Other  ordinary  revenue   117  197  259  221 

Total  Net  Ordinary  Revenue  1,079         1,961         2,650  246 

P.D.P.  (nearest  calendar  year)  15,600       22,200       30,000  192% 

Total    Net    Ordinary    Revenue    as    percentage    of 

P.D.P 6.9%         8.8%  8.8% 

'In  this  chapter,  all  data  relating  to  provincial  revenue,  expenditure  or  debt  are  ex- 
pressed on  a  fiscal  year  basis.  Thus,  in  Table  6:7  above,  the  year  "1964"  includes 
the  period  from  April  1,  1963  to  March  31,  1964. 

186 


Chapter  6:  Paragraphs  52-57 

OTHER  CURRENT  REVENUE 

54.  These  revenues  account  collectively  for  only  10  per  cent  of  the  "net 
ordinary  revenue"  of  the  Province,  being  smaller  in  total  than  the  revenue  derived 
from  any  one  of  the  four  largest  revenue  sources.  For  this  category,  projections 
on  three  separate  bases  were  made:  first,  as  a  proportion  of  P.D.P.;  second,  as  a 
proportion  of  the  net  ordinary  revenue  from  the  eight  sources  less  the  yield  of 
the  personal  income  tax  and  less  the  Province's  share  of  the  federal  estate  tax;  third, 
as  a  simple  projection  of  their  past  trend.  These  three  projections  did  not  differ 
to  any  appreciable  extent.  The  projection  actually  used  is  that  based  on  the  pro- 
portion of  net  ordinary  revenue,  and  the  total  of  "other  current"  revenue  has  been 
projected  at  15  per  cent  of  the  total  yield  of  the  relevant  six  revenue  sources 
indicated  in  this  approach. 

55.  The  figures  shown  in  Table  6:7  require  little  explanation  and  we  offer 
only  one  comment  by  way  of  interpretation.  It  will  be  noted  that  total  net  ordinary 
revenue,  expressed  as  a  percentage  of  P.D.P.,  rises  between  1964  and  1970  but 
that  no  further  change  has  appeared  by  1975.  The  reason  for  the  early  increase  is 
that  some  rates  of  tax,  notably  the  sales  and  gasoline  tax  rates,  were  increased 
during  the  first  period  and  also  that  the  percentage  rebate  from  the  federal  govern- 
ment, with  respect  to  the  personal  income  tax,  rose  between  1963  and  1966.  For 
the  second  period,  1970  to  1975,  the  tax  rates  have  been  assumed  to  remain  un- 
changed. When  this  assumption  is  made,  it  appears  from  the  figures  in  the  last 
line  of  Table  6:7  that  total  net  ordinary  revenue  increases  at  the  same  percentage 
rate  as  does  P.D.P.,  measured  in  current  dollars. 

PROJECTIONS  OF  PROVINCIAL  EXPENDITURE 

56.  In  projecting  provincial  expenditure,  we  shall  consider  the  categories  of 
education,  roads,  health  and  "all  other",  in  each  of  which  we  shall  project 
separately  the  Province's  expenditures  on  current  and  on  capital  account.  In  addi- 
tion, we  note  the  grants  that  the  Province  makes  to  municipalities  and  school 
boards.  These  were  dealt  with  from  the  recipient's  viewpoint  in  our  projections  of 
the  revenues  of  Ontario  municipalities  and  school  boards,  and  the  same  figures, 
now  adjusted  to  a  provincial  fiscal  year  basis,  indicate  the  projected  outlays  of 
the  Province  on  these  grants.  The  remaining  item  of  expenditure,  interest  on  the 
provincial  debt,  will  be  projected  by  means  of  the  same  technique  employed  for 
the  municipalities,  but  the  annual  rate  of  interest  that  we  relate  to  provincial 
debt  is  5  per  cent.  This  rate  of  interest  is  below  that  which  applies  currently  (mid- 
1966)  on  new  borrowing  by  the  Province  but  it  is  in  line  with  the  average  rate 
over  a  longer  period  of  time.  It  should  be  noted  that  the  terms  "current"  and 
"capital"  have  been  used.  These  categories  do  not  correspond  identically  to  the 
"ordinary"  and  "capital"  classifications  used  by  the  Government  of  Ontario  in  its 
accounts. 

EDUCATION 

57.  We  are  concerned  here  with  provincial  expenditure  for  post-secondary 
education  and  v/ith  provincial  contributions  to  teachers'  superannuation  funds. 

187 


Projection  of  Expenditure,  Revenue  and  Debt 

Other  expenditures  on  education  are  included  in  the  provincial  grants  to  school 
boards  and  a  relatively  small  amount  is  found  in  the  residual  item  of  provincial 
expenditure. 

Superannuation 

58.  In  recent  years,  the  provincial  contribution  to  teachers'  superannuation 
funds  has  been  related  partly  to  the  unfunded  portion  of  the  superannuation 
account  and  partly  to  contributions  in  respect  of  teachers'  current  service.  The 
past  service  contribution  in  the  1966  fiscal  year,  and  the  figure  in  the  provincial 
estimates  for  1967,  are  each  just  under  $15  million.  It  is  assumed  that  this  item 
will  remain  at  the  same  level  for  the  duration  of  our  forecast  period. 

59.  The  Province's  contribution  with  respect  to  teachers'  current  service  has 
been  running  at  approximately  6  per  cent  of  total  teaching  salaries  paid  by  the 
elementary  and  secondary  school  boards.  Having  projected  the  future  salary  bill, 
we  assume  that  provincial  contributions  with  respect  to  teachers'  current  service 
will  remain  at  6  per  cent  of  total  teachers'  salaries.  Our  projection  of  total  provin- 
cial contributions  reaches  $65  million  in  the  1975  fiscal  year. 

Post-Secondary  Education 

60.  Our  procedure  in  projecting  the  cost  to  the  Province  of  post-secondary 
education*  has  been  first  to  consider  the  question  of  enrolment,  from  which  we 
have  then  projected  total  costs.  We  then  consider  the  amounts  of  revenue  that  seem 
likely  to  be  forthcoming  from  sources  other  than  the  provincial  treasury.  The 
remainder  of  the  projected  total  cost  of  post-secondary  education  is  then  assumed 
to  be  borne  by  the  Province. 

61.  The  central  and  most  difficult  problem  is  to  project  the  total  enroknent 
in  institutions  of  post-secondary  education  during  the  coming  decade.  For  purposes 
of  making  this  projection,  we  assume  that  institutional  arrangements  as  they  exist 
at  present,  or  as  they  will  be  modified  by  plans  already  publicly  announced  by  the 
government,  will  be  in  effect  throughout  the  period.  More  specifically,  our  pro- 
jections assume  that  Grade  1 3  will  remain  in  existence  as  the  university  preparatory 
year  and  that  teachers  for  elementary  schools  will  be  trained  in  Teachers'  Colleges 
as  they  are  now.  There  is  a  very  high  probability  that  these  assumptions  will  in 
fact  not  be  realized,  but  a  projection  must  begin  from  existing  circumstances.  We 
shall  consider  in  a  later  section  of  this  chapter  the  possible  cost  implications  of 
discontinuing  Grade  13  and  of  requiring  a  university  degree  as  a  qualification  for 
all  newly-qualifying  teachers  in  elementary  schools.  We  also  assume  that  the 
federal  government  will  continue  to  finance  about  the  same  proportion  of  the  cost 
of  post-secondary  education  as  it  has  in  the  past.  There  are  sound  reasons  for 
expecting  that  this  proportion  will  in  fact  increase  in  future,  and  to  the  extent  that 
this  happens,  the  cost  to  the  provincial  treasury  will  be  reduced.  There  are  many 
possibilities  in  this  area  but  it  would  be  fruitless  to  pursue  them  here.    We  shall 

*This  term  is  used  for  convenience  rather  than  with  precise  accuracy.  It  includes 
students  in  full-time  attendance  at  universities,  at  Teachers'  Colleges  and  those 
enrolled  in  full-time  vocational  and  technological  training  courses.  In  all  cases,  we 
are   concerned  only   with  institutions   which   receive   support   from   provincial    funds. 

188 


Chapter  6:  Paragraphs  58-65 

assume,  as  the  only  practicable  course,  that  the  trend  of  past  experience  will  be 
continued  in  the  period  of  our  projection. 

62.  The  Ontario  government  has  recently  announced  that  it  intends  to  intro- 
duce a  province-wide  system  of  Colleges  of  Applied  Arts  and  Technology  and  that 
it  intends  to  proceed  vigorously  with  the  development  of  these  colleges.  We 
assume,  accordingly,  that  there  will  be  a  very  rapid  rate  of  increase  in  the  numbers 
of  students  who  will  be  undertaking  this  type  of  training. 

Enrolment  Projection 

63.  In  dealing  with  the  difficult  question  of  future  enrolments  in  the  various 
types  of  post-secondary  education,  the  most  generally  satisfactory  procedure  seems 
to  be  to  begin  by  projecting  a  total  figure  for  numbers  in  the  whole  range  of  post- 
secondary  education,  as  we  have  defined  that  term,  and  then  to  consider  how  this 
total  seems  likely  to  be  divided  among  the  various  types  of  programs  within  this 
broad  category.  In  the  paragraphs  immediately  following,  we  shall  pass  over  the 
problem  of  post-graduate  enrolment,  returning  to  consider  it  separately  at  a  later 
stage. 

64.  In  the  1965-66  academic  year,  total  enrolment  in  Ontario  post-secondary 
education,  excluding  graduate  students,  was  some  60,000,  or  16  per  cent  of  the 
18-21  year  age  group  of  the  province.  We  have  projected  enrolment  in  1974-75  at 
30  per  cent  of  the  same  age  group,  which  implies  a  total  enrolment  in  that  year  of 
165,000.  In  arriving  at  this  figure,  we  have  examined  past  trends  in  the  percentage 
of  the  age  group  involved  in  some  form  of  post-secondary  education,  as  well  as 
the  number  of  students  who  are  likely  to  be  completing  either  four  or  five  years  of 
high  school.  Although  comparisons  are  difficult,  we  have  also  given  some  attention 
to  comparable  proportions  in  the  United  States.  It  would  be  more  tedious  than 
illuminating  to  offer  a  detailed  account  of  the  methods  that  we  adopted  in  arriving 
at  the  projected  total  enrolment.  As  an  alternative  to  such  detail,  we  simply  note 
that  our  projection  provides  for  about  two-thirds  of  all  those  who  are  expected  to 
enter  Grade  12  to  have  some  form  of  post-secondary  education  and  for  more  than 
80  per  cent  of  those  who  complete  Grade  13  to  proceed  either  to  university  or  to 
Teachers'  Colleges. 

65.  In  evaluating  these  proportions,  it  should  be  kept  in  mind  that  substantial 
numbers  of  students  going  on  to  such  forms  of  post-secondary  education  as  nursing 
or  business  college  will  not  be  included  in  our  figures.  On  the  other  hand,  some 
who  will  be  enrolled  in  an  institution  of  post-secondary  education  will  never  have 
reached  Grade  12  or  will  have  returned  to  some  type  of  post-secondary  education 
after  a  period  away  from  school.  We  must  also  remember  that  at  present  there  are 
about  twice  as  many  men  as  women  in  post-secondary  education  and  that  while 
we  expect  this  imbalance  to  be  reduced  in  the  coming  decade,  it  is  likely  to  remain 
substantial  throughout  the  period  of  our  projection.  To  the  extent  that  this  ten- 
dency persists,  the  proportion  of  all  students  who  proceed  to  further  education  will 
be  lower  than  it  would  be  if  we  were  considering  only  men.  In  view  of  these  con- 
siderations, we  think  that  our  projection  provides  adequately  for  the  numbers  who 

189 


(thousands) 

44 

80 

110 

6 

8 

10 

10 

22 

45 

60 

110 

165 

7 

13 

20 

Projection  of  Expenditure,  Revenue  and  Debt 

will  wish  to  undertake  any  of  the  various  types  of  post-secondary  education  that 
we  have  indicated,  and  who  will  be  qualified  to  do  so. 

66.  Having  projected  a  total  post-secondary  enrolment  of  165,000  students 
by  1974-75,  we  must  next  consider  how  this  total  will  be  distributed  among  the 
various  types  of  institution.  Our  conclusions  concerning  this  matter  are  summarized 
in  Table  6:8. 

Table  6:8 
DISTRIBUTION   OF   POST-SECONDARY   STUDENTS   IN    ONTARIO 

1965*  1969  1974 

University    (undergraduate)    

leachers'  Colleges  

Technical    and    vocational    

Total    

Graduate   

Total  Post-Secondary  Students   67  123  185 

'■'Academic  years  beginning  September. 

67.  The  smallest  relative  increase  is  seen  to  occur  in  Teachers'  Colleges  enrol- 
ment. This  projection  is  related  to  the  number  of  elementary  school  teachers 
required  to  staff  the  schools  of  the  province.  It  provides  for  an  increase  in  the 
total  number  of  elementary  teachers  in  Ontario  schools  and  also  for  replacing 
those  who  withdraw  from  the  teaching  profession. 

68.  Our  projection  of  university  undergraduate  enrolment  is  related  to  the 
number  of  students  who  will  be  completing  the  senior  grades  in  high  school  and  to 
the  proportion  of  these  who  will  proceed  to  university.  We  have  assumed  a  higher 
than  present  retention  rate  in  high  school  and  we  have  also  assumed  that  a  higher 
proportion  of  those  who  are  qualified  to  do  so  will  enter  university. 

69.  Present  enrolment  in  technical  and  vocational  institutions  is  not  large  but 
it  is  expected  to  increase  rapidly  in  the  coming  decade.  From  such  a  small  be- 
ginning, the  projection  of  rapid  growth  is  unusually  difficult  and  in  a  sense  it  is 
correct  to  say  that  we  have  dealt  with  this  difficulty  by  assuming  that  that  part  of 
the  projected  total  enrolment  which  is  not  in  university  or  Teachers'  Colleges  will 
be  in  technical  and  vocational  institutions.  In  other  words,  this  technical  and  voca- 
tional enrolment  has  been  treated  as  the  residual  item.  But  it  should  nevertheless 
be  noted  that  in  1974-75  it  is  450  per  cent  of  1965-66  enrolment,  while  the 
corresponding  figure  for  Teachers'  Colleges  is  167  per  cent  and  for  undergraduate 
university  enrolment,  250  per  cent. 

70.  It  is  assumed  that  by  1974,  technical  and  vocational  training  in  Ontario 
will  be  concentrated  in  some  fifteen  to  twenty  Colleges  of  Applied  Arts  and 
Technology  and  that  enrolment  in  the  individual  colleges  will  average  somewhere 
between  2,000  and  3,000  students.    If  we  assume  that  there  are  between  fifteen 

190 


Chapter  6:  Paragraphs  66-75 

and  twenty  of  these  colleges  in  1974-75,  with  an  average  enrolment  of  2,500  each, 
we  arrive  at  a  total  enrolment  of  between  37,000  and  50,000  students.  Our  pro- 
jected figure  of  45,000  therefore  seems  acceptable. 

71.  As  a  final  note,  it  is  worth  pointing  out  that  the  average  annual  increase 
in  post-secondary  education,  whether  measured  in  absolute  or  relative  terms,  is 
somewhat  more  rapid  in  the  years  before  1969-70  than  in  the  second  part  of  the 
period.  This  provides  additional  confirmation  for  the  widely-recognized  expecta- 
tion that  the  strain  on  the  post-secondary  educational  system  is  Hkely  to  be  at  a 
peak  during  the  remainder  of  this  present  decade.  While  this  is  important  in  rela- 
tion to  the  growth  of  operating  costs,  it  bears  with  particular  force  on  the  financial 
requirements  for  expanding  the  capital  facilities  of  post-secondary  institutions 
within  the  next  very  few  years. 

72.  Our  central  concern  relates  to  future  financial  requirements  in  provincial 
education  and  it  is  in  this  context  that  we  have  projected  the  future  trend  of  enrol- 
ments. Having  done  so,  we  now  proceed  to  estimate  the  operating  cost  per  student, 
after  which  we  calculate  the  total  operating  cost  for  each  type  of  institution  in  each 
year.  Enrolment  figures  also  provide  a  means  of  estimating  the  number  of  addi- 
tional places  that  must  be  forthcoming,  and  after  deriving  an  estimate  of  the  capital 
cost  per  place,  we  can  then  project  the  total  capital  cost  in  each  year.  We  shall 
deal  first  with  the  operating  and  capital  costs  of  universities,  both  for  undergraduate 
and  graduate  students,  then  proceed  to  the  Teachers'  Colleges  and  finally  consider 
the  Colleges  of  Applied  Arts  and  Technology. 

University  Costs — Operating 

73.  In  dealing  with  the  operating  costs  of  universities,  we  must  consider 
graduate  and  undergraduate  costs  together,  since  it  is  not  possible  to  separate 
them.  We  shall  assume  that  operating  costs  per  graduate  student  are,  on  the 
average,  three  times  those  for  an  undergraduate  and  we  shall,  for  purposes  of 
projecting  operating  costs,  deal  in  terms  of  the  equivalent  number  of  undergraduate 
students.  We  assign  to  each  graduate  student  a  weight  of  three,  compared  with  a 
weight  of  one  for  each  undergraduate.  Our  cost  figures  will  therefore  be  expressed 
as  the  operating  cost  per  year  per  equivalent  undergraduate  student. 

74.  Proceeding  on  this  basis,  we  find  that  the  operating  cost  per  equivalent 
undergraduate  student,  in  the  university  year  1963-64,  was  just  under  $1,900.  We 
assume  that  this  cost  will  rise  at  6  per  cent  per  annum,  being  therefore  slightly 
above  $3,500  per  student  by  1974-75.  This  annual  rate  of  increase  is  almost 
exactly  equal  to  that  of  the  past  few  years,  and  in  view  of  the  rapid  expansion  that 
will  be  experienced  in  this  area  in  the  coming  decade,  we  do  not  expect  it  to 
moderate.  On  this  basis,  we  arrive  at  a  figure  of  $602  million  in  1974-75,  as  the 
total  of  operating  costs  of  provincially  assisted  universities  in  Ontario. 

75.  These  costs  will,  of  course,  not  be  met  entirely  by  the  provincial  govern- 
ment. Universities  also  receive  income  from  students'  fees,  from  the  federal 
government  and  from  other  sources  such  as  endowments,  municipal  governments 
and  gifts.  We  assume  that  fees  per  student  will  increase  over  the  period  at  the  same 

191 


Projection  of  Expenditure,  Revenue  and  Debt 

rate  as  per-capita  income,  i.e.,  4  per  cent  per  annum.  Having  assumed  that  opera- 
ting costs  per  student  will  increase  at  6  per  cent  per  annum,  we  conclude  that  fees 
will  cover  a  declining  proportion  of  university  operating  costs.  The  proportion  in 
1963-64  was  24  per  cent,  and  given  our  assumptions,  it  will  have  fallen  to  15  per 
cent  by  1974-75. 

76.  The  federal  government  supports  universities  chiefly  through  its  per-capita 
grant  and  through  support  for  university  research.  In  the  past,  total  federal  con- 
tributions have  approximated  25  per  cent  of  university  current  operating  costs. 
The  increase  in  per-capita  grant  to  $5  in  1966-67  will,  at  least  temporarily,  bring 
federal  support  to  a  somewhat  higher  proportion  than  formerly.  However,  if  no 
further  changes  are  made,  this  proportion  will  decline  again  as  university  operating 
costs  increase  at  a  more  rapid  rate  than  population.  We  think  it  highly  probable 
that  further  increases,  in  one  form  or  another,  will  be  necessary,  but  since  it  is  not 
our  purpose  to  forecast  changes  in  either  federal  or  provincial  government  policy, 
we  assume  that  the  federal  contribution,  while  increasing  in  dollar  amount  after 
1966-67,  will  remain  at  25  per  cent  of  the  universities'  total  current  operating  costs. 

77.  Revenues  from  other  sources  now  provide  about  one-eighth  of  university 
operating  costs.  We  expect  that  contributions  from  these  sources  will  increase  at 
the  same  rate  as  P.D.P.  Since  university  operating  costs  will  be  increasing  at  a 
considerably  more  rapid  rate,  the  relative  importance  of  such  funds  will  decline. 
Thus,  according  to  our  projection,  revenue  from  these  sources  will  by  1974-75 
account  for  only  5  per  cent  of  total  current  operating  costs,  although  in  absolute 
amount  they  will  have  become  almost  twice  as  large  as  they  were  in  1963-64. 

78.  We  assume  that  the  remainder  of  the  universities'  operating  expenditures 
will  be  met  by  provincial  grants.  From  a  level  of  $36  million  in  1963-64,  our 
figures  show  such  grants  increasing  to  $153  million  in  1969-70  and  to  $328  million 
for  1974-75. 

University  Costs — Capital 

79.  The  cost  of  each  new  undergraduate  place  to  the  provincial  government 
averaged  an  estimated  $7,150  in  1964-65.  We  have  assumed  that  this  figure  will 
increase  at  5  per  cent  per  annum  (2  per  cent  because  of  price  increases  and  3  per 
cent  reflecting  the  eff^ects  of  the  greater  complexity  and  the  rising  standards  of 
modern  university  facilities).  We  have  projected  annually  the  cost  of  providing 
the  additional  places  for  the  increased  enrolment  expected  in  the  following  year, 
in  accordance  with  our  projected  enrolment  figures.  We  have  projected  capital 
costs  for  graduate  places  in  a  similar  manner,  but  we  have  assumed  that  one 
graduate  place  will  cost  twice  as  much,  on  the  average,  as  an  undergraduate  place. 

80.  In  many  instances,  a  building  program  will  involve  capital  expenditure 
some  time  in  advance  of  the  increase  in  enrolment.  We  have  therefore  increased 
the  figures  in  our  projection  in  the  early  years  of  the  period,  both  to  allow  for  this 
factor  and  to  bring  our  figures  more  closely  into  line  with  the  level  of  recent  capital 
expenditure  and  that  anticipated  in  the  near  future.  This  procedure  implies  that  we 
might  have  reduced  the  figures  for  later  years.    We  have  chosen  not  to  do  so,  in 

192 


Chapter  6:  Paragraphs  76-86 

order  to  provide  a  margin  for  unexpected  and  possible  costly  future  developments 
and  also  to  recognize  the  fact  that  the  distribution  of  university  enrolments  and 
university  places  may  not  always  be  perfectly  correlated. 

8 1 .  Our  figures  also  encompass  provincial  grants  with  respect  to  the  provision 
of  additional  university  residence  accommodation.  The  amounts  involved  are 
relatively  small  because  Central  Mortgage  and  Housing  Corporation  loans  are 
available  to  cover  a  large  part  of  the  costs  and  no  detailed  account  of  their  deriva- 
tion therefore  seems  necessary.  We  think  the  maximum  level  attained  by  these 
grants  will  be  $5  million  in  1974-75. 

82.  The  total  projected  cost  to  the  Province  for  capital  grants  to  universities 
for  graduate,  undergraduate  and  residence  places  over  the  period  1966-67  to 
1974-75  is  $982  million.  As  we  would  have  expected,  these  outlays  in  the  late 
1960's  are  at  a  somewhat  higher  level  than  those  in  the  first  half  of  the  1970's,  a 
circumstance  reflecting  the  pattern  of  enrolment  increases  over  the  period. 

Teachers'  Colleges — Operating  and  Capital  Costs 

83.  Teachers'  College  enrolment  in  1965-66  was  approximately  6,000,  and  we 
have  projected  an  increase  to  10,000  by  1974-75,  if  present  arrangements  for  the 
training  of  teachers  for  elementary  schools  are  continued  until  that  time.  The 
operating  cost  per  student  in  1965-66  was  very  close  to  $1,000,  and  this  is  expected 
to  increase  at  6  per  cent  per  annum.  On  these  assumptions,  the  total  annual 
operating  costs  of  Teachers'  Colleges  would  be  $18  million  by  1974-75. 

84.  Capital  costs  will  be  incurred  to  provide  the  increased  number  of  places, 
but  the  disappearance  of  the  two-year  program  for  training  teachers  should  mean 
that  little  capital  expenditure  will  be  required  in  the  immediate  future.  Our  projec- 
tion provides  for  a  total  of  $40  million  to  the  end  of  the  1974-75  fiscal  year,  with 
annual  expenditure  running  at  $5  to  $7  million  in  the  last  five  years  of  the  period. 

Colleges  of  Applied  Arts  and  Technology — Operating  Costs 

85.  The  introduction  of  these  colleges  is  an  innovation  of  major  importance 
to  education  in  Ontario,  and  it  seems  evident  that  they  will  develop  at  a  rapid  rate 
over  the  next  decade.  However,  the  federal  government  can  be  expected  to  pay 
close  to  half  of  the  costs  involved,  and  the  impact  on  Ontario's  provincial  finances 
will  thereby  be  correspondingly  reduced.  Parenthetically,  we  note  that  there  will 
be  a  similar  fortunate  reduction  in  the  effect  of  any  error  in  our  projections  con- 
cerning these  colleges.  We  do  wish  to  make  very  clear,  however,  that  because  we 
are  dealing  with  a  potentially  very  large  undertaking  which  is  still  in  its  initial 
stages,  these  cost  projections  have  an  unavoidable  large  margin  of  error. 

86.  In  1965-66,  the  full-time  enrolment  in  provincial  institutions  such  as 
Institutes  of  Technology  and  Institutes  of  Trades  was  10,000  students.  It  is 
assumed  that  in  the  future  such  training  will  be  provided  by  the  new  Colleges  of 
Applied  Arts  and  Technology  and  that,  as  mentioned  above,  enrolment  in  these 
colleges  will  reach  45,000  students  by  1974-75.  The  operating  cost  per  full-time 
student  now  somewhat  exceeds  $1,000,  but  fees  payable  by  the  student  reduce 

193 


Projection  of  Expenditure,  Revenue  and  Debt 

the  cost  to  government  to  this  approximate  level.   We  assume  that  this  per-student 
cost  will  increase  by  6  per  cent  per  annum,  to  $1,700  in  1974-75. 

87.  This  calculation  represents  a  total  annual  operating  cost  of  $76  million  a 
year  by  the  end  of  our  forecast  period.  The  federal  government  can  be  expected 
to  pay  50  per  cent  of  the  cost  of  vocational  training,  but  we  assume  that  some 
parts  of  the  program  of  these  colleges  may  not  qualify  for  federal  support  on  this 
basis  and  we  have  accordingly  assumed  that  Ontario's  share  will  be  60  per  cent 
of  the  total  cost.   In  1974-75,  this  share  will  approximate  $44  million. 

Colleges  of  Applied  Arts  and  Technology — Capital  Costs 

88.  The  method  of  projecting  these  costs  is  similar  to  that  employed  in  uni- 
versity capital  costs.  We  estimate  the  cost  per  place  at  $4,500  in  1965-66  and  we 
assume  that  this  figure  will  increase  by  5  per  cent  per  annum.  As  with  operating 
costs,  we  have  allocated  40  per  cent  to  the  federal  government,  leaving  the 
provincial  government  to  provide  the  remaining  60  per  cent  of  the  cost.  The  total 
capital  cost  to  the  end  of  the  1975  fiscal  year  has  been  projected  at  $275  million, 
of  which  Ontario  would  pay  $165  million.  The  maximum  cost  in  any  one  year, 
according  to  our  calculations,  is  $30  million. 

Debt  Service  Charges 

89.  Provincial  capital  grants  to  Ontario  universities  are  now  made  by  the 
Ontario  Universities  Capital  Aid  Corporation,  which  receives  funds  from  the 
Province  and  makes  loans  to  the  universities.  The  universities  pay  interest  on  their 
accumulated  debt  at  5Vi  per  cent  per  annum  and  repay  annually  one-thirtieth  of 

Table  6:9 
COSTS  TO  THE  GOVERNMENT  OF  ONTARIO  OF  POST-SECONDARY  EDUCATION 


1964*  1970  1975 


Current 

Universities     

Teachers'  Col  leges   

Technical,  vocational  and  other  post-secondary 
education     

Total  Current  Cost  

Capital 

Universities   (including  residences)    

Teachers'  Col  leges   

Technical,  vocational  and  other  post-secondary 
education   

Total  Capital  Cost 

Total  Cost  

Teachers'  Superannuation  (not  included  above)   .   . 
Debt  Service  Grants  (not  included  above)   


(millions  of  dollars) 

36 

153 

328 

4 

9 

18 

4 

17 

44 

44 

179 

390 

36 

103 

130 

— 

5 

7 

1 

20 

30 

37 

128 

167 

81 

307 

557 

= 

=:= 

21 

50 

65 



42 

74 

^Fiscal  years. 

194 


Chapter  6:  Paragraphs  87-93 

the  capital  amount  of  any  grant,  for  thirty  years.  The  Province,  in  determining 
operating  grants  for  the  universities,  includes  an  amount  to  provide  for  the  debt 
service  charges,  i.e.,  interest  plus  principal  repayments.  While  this  arrangement 
makes  it  possible  for  the  Province  to  treat  capital  grants  to  universities  as  capital 
loans  rather  than  current  expenditure,  it  affects  the  form  rather  than  the  substance 
of  provincial  capital  aid  to  universities. 

90.  Our  projections  show  that  by  the  end  of  1974-75,  the  accumulated  debt 
owed  by  the  universities  to  the  Province  will  be  $952  million.  In  that  fiscal  year, 
total  debt  service  payments  will  be  $74  million,  comprising  $46  million  interest 
and  $28  million  debt  repayment. 

Cost  Implications  of  Some  Possible  Changes  in  the  System  of  Education 

9 1 .  Our  projections  have  been  made  on  the  assumption  that  arrangements  now 
in  existence,  or  policies  already  announced  by  the  government,  will  remain  in  effect 
throughout  the  period.  This  assumption,  while  necessary,  is  probably  not  entirely 
realistic,  and  we  therefore  wish  to  consider  briefly  the  implications  for  our  projec- 
tions of  two  mooted  changes  which  may  quite  possibly  occur  before  1975.  The 
first  is  that  the  present  Grade  13  may  not  be  in  existence  in  ten  years'  time,  and 
the  second  is  that  a  university  degree  may  be  required  for  newly-qualifying  ele- 
mentary school  teachers  before  1975.  The  effects  of  such  changes  on  our 
projections  of  cost  seem  unlikely  to  be  very  great. 

92.  The  reduction  of  the  high  school  program  from  five  years  to  four  will 
reduce  the  costs  to  the  secondary  school  system  below  what  they  would  have  been 
if  this  reduction  had  not  occurred.  On  the  other  hand,  the  costs  of  post-secondary 
education  will  tend  to  be  increased,  to  the  extent  that  more  students  than  would 
otherwise  have  done  so  undertake  such  education,  or  to  the  extent  that  students 
require  longer  to  complete  a  given  post-secondary  educational  program  if  the  high 
school  course  is  reduced  to  four  years.  If  students  go  to  Colleges  of  Applied  Arts 
and  Technology  for  an  added  year,  the  net  cost  to  the  provincial  and  municipal 
governments  would  probably  be  less  than  if  they  remained  in  high  school  for 
another  year.  The  total  cost  of  a  year  at  a  College  of  Applied  Arts  and  Technology 
would  probably  be  greater  than  that  of  a  year  in  the  present  Grade  13,  but  after 
allowance  for  the  fees  paid  by  the  student  and  for  the  federal  grant,  the  net  cost  to 
the  provincial  government  and  the  school  boards  would  almost  certainly  be  less. 

93.  It  is  probable,  however,  that  most  students  who  would  be  completing  the 
present  Grade  13  would  plan  to  enter  university.  Here  several  possible  cost 
implications  require  consideration.  First,  more  students  may  enter  university  if  the 
high  school  program  is  only  four  years.  However,  we  have  allowed  in  our  projec- 
tion both  for  a  higher  retention  rate  in  high  school  and  for  a  larger  proportion  of 
students  continuing  on  to  university.  We  think  that  our  projections  of  the  number 
of  students  who  will  enter  university  would  not  have  been  much  higher  had  we 
assumed  a  four-year  high  school  preparation  for  university.  Second,  the  shorter 
high  school  course  might  entail  a  longer  university  course.  If  the  reduction  of  one 
year  in  the  high  school  course  required  the  addition  of  one  year  to  each  university 

195 


Projection  of  Expenditure,  Revenue  and  Debt 

course,  university  costs  would  clearly  be  increased.  The  increase  would  neverthe- 
less be  not  as  great  as  might  first  appear.  The  difference  between  the  cost  of  a  year 
in  Grade  13  and  of  an  additional  year  at  the  beginning  of  a  university  course  is 
much  less  than  the  difference  between  the  average  cost  of  a  university  year  and 
the  average  cost  of  a  high  school  year.  Moreover,  because  we  are  concerned  here 
with  the  cost  to  public  authorities,  we  must  consider  the  effect  of  students'  fees  in 
reducing  this  cost.  If  the  reduction  in  the  length  of  the  high  school  course  does  not 
lead  to  an  equivalent  increase  in  the  length  of  university  courses,  any  net  increase 
in  the  cost  of  education  would  appear  not  to  be  great. 

94.  In  summary,  we  believe  that  if  the  high  school  program  were  reduced  to 
four  years,  the  net  increase  to  the  various  public  authorities  in  the  cost  of  providing 
education  would  not  be  very  great.  It  is  even  possible  that  the  cost  would  be  lower 
than  if  the  present  five-year  program  is  retained. 

95.  The  second  possible  change  in  educational  policy  is  that  elementary  school 
teachers'  qualifications  will  include  a  university  degree.  Should  this  occur, 
economies  would  arise  from  the  fact  that  the  present  Teachers'  Colleges  would 
probably  be  incorporated  into  the  university  system.  In  the  new  system  students 
might  be  required  to  have  a  four-year  high  school  course  plus  a  three-year  uni- 
versity course,  in  order  to  qualify  as  elementary  school  teachers.  At  present,  the 
requirement  involves  a  five-year  high  school  course  plus  one  year  at  Teachers' 
College.  The  new  system  would  require  one  additional  year  and  total  costs  would 
therefore  rise.  We  must,  however,  take  into  account  the  fees  paid  by  university 
students  (fees  are  not  charged  at  Teachers'  Colleges  or  at  high  schools),  a  circum- 
stance that  substantially  changes  the  cost  picture.  Moreover,  if  a  university  degree 
were  required  for  an  elementary  school  teacher's  certificate,  it  is  probable  that  some 
students  would  take  the  course  for  teachers  who  would  not  otherwise  have  done  so. 
On  balance,  we  would  expect  that  this  change  would  at  most  occasion  only  a  slight 
increase  in  teacher  training  costs.  It  would,  however,  be  necessary  to  increase  the 
total  amount  of  scholarship  and  bursary  aid,  and,  possibly  more  important  from  the 
standpoint  of  cost,  the  average  salary  for  elementary  school  teachers  would  be 
increased  if  a  university  degree  were  required. 

96.  The  effect  on  capital  costs  of  a  shortened  secondary  school  course  and  of 
university  training  for  elementary  teachers  also  requires  consideration.  Economies 
would  be  realized  in  that  high  school  and  Teachers'  College  facilities,  both  present 
and  projected,  would  in  many  localities  be  used  by  universities.  There  would 
nevertheless  still  be  some  need  for  additional  capital  expenditures  by  the  educa- 
tional system  as  a  whole.  We  have  already  noted  that  in  our  projection  of  university 
capital  expenditure,  allowance  has  been  made  for  a  limited  increase  of  university 
places  beyond  the  projected  student  enrolment.  Possibly  this  modest  excess  could 
be  somewhat  reduced  if  the  changes  we  have  mentioned  were  to  be  introduced. 

97.  Our  conclusion,  then,  is  that  the  introduction  of  the  foregoing  changes 
would  on  balance  probably  increase  slightly  both  the  operating  costs  and  the  capital 
costs  of  education  to  the  public  authorities.  But  if  we  had  made  our  projections  on 
the  assumption  that  both  of  these  changes  were  to  be  made,  we  think  that  they 

196 


Chapter  6:  Paragraphs  94-99 

would  not  have  been  increased  by  any  large  proportion.  We  are  of  the  opinion 
that  the  increase  would  not  have  exceeded  10  per  cent,  and  we  regard  5  per  cent 
as  a  much  better  estimate  of  its  magnitude.  Thus,  while  our  projections  have  been 
made  in  the  light  of  the  present  form  of  the  educational  system,  we  think  that  their 
general  validity  would  not  be  very  greatly  affected  by  the  two  major  changes  that 
now  seem  most  likely  to  be  introduced  in  the  period  with  which  we  are  concerned. 

HIGHWAYS  AND  ROADS 

98.  In  the  past,  provincial  expenditure  on  highways,  including  grants  to 
municipalities  for  roads,  streets  and  related  items,  has  corresponded  closely  to  the 
revenue  from  the  gasoline  tax  and  from  motor  vehicle  licences  and  permits.  For 
the  1967  fiscal  year,  this  expenditure,  as  forecast  in  the  1966  Budget  papers, 
amounted  to  109  per  cent  of  such  revenue.  By  coincidence,  this  ratio  represents 
the  average  for  the  fiscal  years  1958-59  to  1965-66.  Consequently,  on  the  basis 
of  our  projections  of  annual  gasoline  tax  and  motor  vehicle  revenues,  we  project 
109  per  cent  of  these  amounts  in  each  year  as  representing  total  provincial  expen- 
diture, in  constant  dollars,  on  highways  and  roads. 

Table  6: 10 
GOVERNMENT  OF  ONTARIO   EXPENDITURES   ON   HIGHWAYS   AND   ROADS 

1975 
as  a 
percentage 
1964         1970         1975       of  1964 


(millions  of  dollars) 


Provincial  Expenditure  on  Current  Account 

Expenditure  on  own  account  49  67  81         165% 

Grants  to  municipalities  re  current 

expenditure  on  roads,  streets,  etc 33  47  61         185 

Total  Current  Account  Expenditure  82  114  142         173 

Provincial  Expenditure  on  Capital  Account 

Expenditure  on  own  account  143  224  306         214 

Grants  to  municipalities  re  capital  expenditure 

on  roads,  streets,  etc 55  90  126         229 

Total  Capital  Account  Expenditure   198  314  432         218 


Total  Expenditure    280  428  574         205% 


99.  This  projection  of  expenditure  is  in  effect  in  constant  dollars,  because  the 
revenue  to  which  it  relates  is  based  on  the  physical  quantity  of  gasoline  on  which 
tax  is  collected  and  on  the  number  of  all  licensed  motor  vehicles.  But  whereas 
the  bases  of  the  gasoline  tax  and  motor  vehicle  licences  do  not  increase  with  the 
price  level,  the  cost  of  building  and  repairing  highways  and  roads  is  directly 
affected  by  price  level  changes.  In  the  past,  the  Province  has  met  this  situation  by 
increasing  its  rates  of  tax  from  time  to  time.  Because  we  have  assumed  throughout 
our  projections  that  tax  rates  remain  unchanged,  it  is  apparent  that,  in  conjunction 
with  continuing  increases  in  highway  construction  costs,  the  projected  gasoline  and 

197 


Projection  of  Expenditure,  Revenue  and  Debt 

motor  vehicle  revenue  is  unlikely  to  be  sufficient  to  come  within  9  per  cent  of  the 
expenditures  involved.  To  meet  this  problem,  we  have  assumed  that  general  road 
costs  will  rise  by  the  2  per  cent  per  annum  that  we  have  projected  for  other  costs 
and  we  have  combined  this  factor  with  our  109  per  cent  of  projected  revenue  to 
arrive  at  the  figure  for  total  spending  by  the  Province  on  highways  and  related 
services, 

100.  We  have  broken  down  the  resulting  aggregate  into  its  current  and  capital 
components,  and  we  have  in  turn  subdivided  these  components  into  direct  provin- 
cial expenditure  and  provincial  grants  to  municipaUties.  These  allocations  are 
based  on  the  proportions  in  which  aggregate  highways  expenditure  has  been  divided 
among  these  four  categories  in  the  recent  past,  modified  in  the  light  of  advice 
provided  by  the  Ontario  Department  of  Highways.  In  general,  while  we  have 
introduced  no  sharp  changes  in  the  proportions,  our  projection  displays  a  tendency 
toward  a  somewhat  larger  proportion  of  expenditure  on  capital  account,  both  for 
the  Province's  own  purposes  and  in  its  grants  to  municipalities. 

HEALTH 

101.  Three  categories  of  provincial  health  expenditure  require  individual 
attention:  the  government  contribution  to  the  Ontario  Hospital  Care  Insurance 
Plan,  the  operating  and  maintenance  costs  of  Ontario  Hospitals,  and  subsidies  for 
the  premiums  of  low-income  participants  in  the  Ontario  Medical  Services  Insurance 
Plan. 

Provincial  Contributions  to  the  Ontario  Hospital  Services  Commission 

102.  In  the  three  fiscal  years  1965  to  1967,  Ontario  government  contributions 
plus  individual  premiums  have  averaged  59  per  cent  of  the  total  expenditures  of  the 
Ontario  Hospital  Services  Commission.  We  have  examined  an  Ontario  Hospital 
Services  Commission  projection  of  total  expenditure  to  the  end  of  1971  and,  after 
extrapolating  it  to  the  end  of  our  forecast  period,  have  adopted  it  for  our  purposes. 
We  have  assumed  that,  in  line  with  recent  experience,  the  sum  of  provincial  con- 
tributions plus  individual  premiums  will  cover  60  per  cent  of  the  total  expenditure 
of  the  Ontario  Hospital  Services  Commission.  In  1964,  the  individual  premium 
rate  was  increased  so  that  premiums  would  cover  about  40  per  cent  of  total  cost, 
rather  than  the  slightly  less  than  30  per  cent  covered  at  the  former  premium  level. 

103.  We  further  assume  that  premiums  will  again  be  increased  to  maintain 
this  40  per  cent  share  whenever  Ontario  Hospital  Services  Commission  premium 
income  falls  below  a  35  per  cent  ratio.  This  policy  implies  further  increases  in 
1970  and  again  in  1974.  The  remaining  share  of  the  60  per  cent  of  Ontario 
Hospital  Services  Commission  total  expenditure  will  continue  to  be  covered  by 
contributions  from  the  provincial  government  which,  according  to  our  projection, 
will  amount  to  $100  million  in  1970  and  $141  million  in  1975.  Included  in  these 
provincial  contributions  are  capital  grants  for  hospital  construction,  which  were 
$12  million  in  1964  and  averaged  $16  million  per  annum  in  the  four  years  ending 
1967.  We  have  projected  these  capital  grants  at  $22  million  in  1970  and  at  $27 
million  in  1975. 

198 


Chapter  6:  Paragraphs  100-106 

Table  6: 11 

GOVERNMENT  OF  ONTARIO  EXPENDITURES  ON  HOSPITALS  AND  HEALTH- 
MAJOR  ITEMS 


1975 
as  a 
percentage 
1964  1970         1975       of  1964 


(millions  of  dollars) 


Provincial  contributions  to  Ontario  Hospital  Services 

Commission*     45  100  141  313% 

Ontario  Hospitals — operation  and  maintenance  61  102  146  239 

Premium  subsidies — Ontario  Medical  Services  In- 
surance Plan  —  99  145           — 

Total    106  301  432  408% 


^Includes  grants  for  hospital  construction  of  $12  million  in  1964,  $22  million  in  1970  and 
$27  million  in  1975. 

Operation  and  Maintenance  of  Ontario  Hospitals 

104.  In  the  past  five  years,  the  rate  of  increase  in  provincial  operating  and 
maintenance  grants  to  Ontario  Hospitals  has  been  very  slightly  less  than  the  rate 
of  increase  in  expenditures  by  the  Ontario  Hospital  Services  Commission.  We 
would  have  projected  the  same  rate  of  increase  for  Ontario  Hospitals  as  for  the 
Ontario  Hospital  Services  Commission  except  for  the  fact  that  the  Province  now 
proposes  to  provide  more  mental  health  care  in  local  general  hospitals.  This  will 
involve  some  increase  in  the  cost  of  such  care  and  we  have  consequently  provided 
for  a  somewhat  more  rapid  rate  of  increase  in  provincial  expenditure  on  mental 
health  than  for  the  Ontario  Hospital  Services  Commission.  Operating  and  main- 
tenance expenditure  of  Ontario  Hospitals  was  $61  milUon  in  1964;  our  projected 
figure  for  the  comparable  expenditure,  whether  in  Ontario  Hospitals  or  elsewhere, 
is  $146  million  in  1975. 

105.  Considering  the  actual  and  projected  provincial  contributions  to  the 
Ontario  Hospital  Services  Commission,  plus  the  operation  and  maintenance  of 
Ontario  Hospitals,  we  find  that  these  expenditures  will  average  35  per  cent  of  the 
total  cost  of  these  two  services  from  1964  to  1975.  This  proportion  is  very  close 
to  the  one-third  which  the  Provincial  Treasurer,  in  his  1964  Budget  Speech, 
indicated  to  be  the  approximate  proportion  which  the  provincial  government 
believed  that  it  should  contribute.  Our  projection  is  therefore  in  line  both  with 
past  trends  and  with  present  government  policy. 

106.  The  Ontario  Medical  Services  Insurance  Plan  came  into  effect  on  July  1, 
1966.  Under  this  plan,  provision  has  been  made  to  cover  from  public  funds  part 
or  all  of  the  premiums  payable  by  those  members  with  low  incomes  and  for  those 
receiving  welfare  assistance.  The  government  has  estimated  the  cost  of  premium 
assistance  from  July  1,  1966,  to  March  31,  1967,  as  $58.9  million,  a  figure  that 
corresponds  to  some  $78  million  for  a  full  fiscal  year.  We  have  provided,  in  our 
projection,  for  an  increase  in  the  number  of  those  persons  who  will  receive  premium 
assistance  as  provincial  population  increases,  and  we  have  also  provided  for  an 

199 


Projection  of  Expenditure,  Revenue  and  Debt 

increase  in  premium  levels,  at  the  rate  of  6  per  cent  per  annum.    The  projected 
cost  to  the  Province  for  this  premium  assistance  is  $145  million  in  1975. 

CONSTRUCTION  OF  PUBLIC  BUILDINGS 

107.  This  item  has  varied  greatly  from  year  to  year.  The  provincial  estimates 
indicate  a  figure  of  $41  million  for  1967  and  we  assume  a  subsequent  increase  of 
5  per  cent  per  year,  a  rate  in  line  with  past  experience.  Our  projected  expenditure 
is  $60  million  in  1975. 

OTHER  CAPITAL  EXPENDITURE 

108.  The  major  components  of  this  relatively  small  outlay  are  capital  expen- 
ditures for  provincial  parks  and  for  conservation.  Total  outlays  have  averaged 
some  $10  million  in  recent  years  and  have  been  increasing  relatively  rapidly.  We 
are  projecting  a  continuing  rapid  increase  to  $39  million  in  1975. 

OTHER  CURRENT  EXPENDITURE 

109.  This  is  a  residual  category  that  includes  all  items  of  current  expenditure 
not  projected  individually,  except  interest  on  the  provincial  debt.  Apart  from  most 
of  the  costs  of  general  provincial  administration,  this  category  embraces  many 
smaller  individual  items  of  expenditure  which  it  is  neither  feasible  nor  necessary 
to  project  individually. 

110.  Our  procedure  in  projecting  the  total  of  residual  expenditures  was  to 
examine  the  historical  record  back  to  1960  for  several  of  the  larger  individual 
items  not  affected  by  major  policy  changes  during  the  period  analysed.  The  total 
for  these  selected  items  was  found  to  have  increased  at  an  average  annual  rate  of 
just  under  8  per  cent  between  1960  and  1967. 

111.  This  rate  of  increase  seems  reasonable  in  the  light  of  more  general  con- 
siderations. A  large  share  of  residual  expenditures  represents  salaries,  and  here  we 
expect  an  average  increase  of  from  4  to  5  per  cent  per  annum.  We  have  assumed 
that  other  costs  will  increase  by  2  per  cent  annually,  so  that  the  weighted  average 
annual  increase  in  the  relevant  price  level  (since  wages  and  salaries  represent  the 
major  share  of  the  total)  would  appear  to  be  from  3Vi  to  4  per  cent.  In  addition, 
the  Ontario  population  is  expected  to  grow  at  about  2  per  cent  per  annum. 
Provision  must  also  be  made  for  minor  but,  given  our  underlying  assumptions,  not 
for  major  extensions  and  modifications  in  existing  programs.  Finally,  we  must 
allow  for  the  "improvement  factor"  in  public  services,  which  we  view  as  the  counter- 
part of  a  rising  average  standard  of  consumption  in  the  private  sector  of  the 
economy.  When  all  of  these  factors  are  taken  into  account,  and  some  allowance 
made  for  overlapping,  it  appears  that  an  average  rate  of  increase  of  from  7  to  8 
per  cent  would  be  expected.  We  have  therefore  made  our  projection  on  the  assump- 
tion that  residual  items  of  expenditure  on  current  account  will  increase  at  a  rate 
of  8  per  cent  a  year,  from  a  1967  total  of  $432  million  to  $800  million  in  1975. 

GRANTS  TO  MUNICIPALITIES  AND  SCHOOL  BOARDS 

112.  We  have  already  projected  the  amount  of  these  grants,  from  the  income 
side,  in  our  analysis  of  municipal  and  school  board  revenues.  The  same  projections 

200 


Chapter  6:  Paragraphs  107-1 14 

have  been  adjusted  to  a  provincial  fiscal  year  basis  to  provide  us  with  the  trend  of 
annual  provincial  expenditures  on  these  grants. 

PROJECTION  OF  PROVINCIAL  BUDGETARY  AND 
DEBT  POSITION 

113.  In  Table  6:12  we  have  brought  together,  for  selected  fiscal  years,  our 
projections  of  revenue,  expenditure  and  debt.  The  structure  of  this  Table  parallels 
that  of  Table  6:6,  which  provides  comparable  information  for  local  governments. 

Table  6:12 
BUDGETARY  AND  DEBT  POSITION  OF  THE  GOVERNMENT  OF  ONTARIO 

1975 
as  a 
percentage 
1964         1970         1975       of  1964 

(millions  of  dollars) 
Revenue 

1.  Provincial   net  ordinary  revenue    1,079  1,961         2,650         246% 

2.  Debt  service  payments  from  universities  ..  —  42  74  — 

3.  Total  1,079         2,003         2,724         252 

Current  Expenditure 

4.  Ordinary   expenditure    (excluding   interest 

payments  and  transfers  to  local  govern- 
ments)       450         1,161  1,815         403 

5.  Transfers    to    local    governments    re:    ex- 

penditure on   current   account    296  547  784         265 

6.  Interest    61  119  275         451 

7.  Total  Current  Account  Expenditure  807         1,827         2,874         356 

8.  Surplus  on  Current  Account  272  176        —150 

Capital  Expenditure 

9.  Capital  expenditure  (excluding  transfers  to 

local    governments)    227  442  599         264 

10.  Transfers    to    local    governments    re:    ex- 

penditure on  capital  account  106  177  249         235 

11.  Total  Capital  Account  Expenditure  333  619  848         255 

12.  Deficit  (=  increase  in  debt)    61  443  998 

13.  Net  Capital  Debt  at  end  of  period*   1,345         2,898         6,575         489 

14.  Provincial  Domestic  Product  (nearest  calendar 

year)    15,600       22,200       30,000         192 

15.  Net  Capital  Debt  as  percentage  of  P.  D.  P 8.6%        13.1%       21.9% 

'•'Includes  $559  million  in  1970  and  $952  million  in  1975  owing  by  universities  to  Ontario 
Universities  Capital  Aid  Corporation. 

114.  The  most  striking  feature  of  Table  6:12  is  the  very  large  projected 
increase  in  the  net  capital  debt  of  the  Province.  More  detailed  figures  provided  in 
the  Appendix  to  this  chapter  reveal  that  within  less  than  a  decade,  from  1967  to 
1975,  a  four-fold  increase  will  have  occurred.  In  recent  years  this  debt  has  ranged 
from  8  to  9  per  cent  of  provincial  domestic  product,  but  our  figures  show  this  ratio 

201 


Projection  of  Expenditure,  Revenue  and  Debt 

increasing  to  almost  22  per  cent  by  the  end  of  the  forecast  period.  Moreover,  the 
trend  of  this  debt  ratio  shows  no  tendency  to  flatten  out  in  the  later  years  with 
which  we  deal;  on  the  contrary,  an  extrapolation  of  the  trend  projected  for  the  early 
1970's  indicates  that  the  ratio  will  reach  30  per  cent  as  early  as  1979. 

115.  Three  factors  may  be  mentioned  as  responsible  for  the  projected  increase 
in  provincial  debt.  The  first  is  the  general  circumstance  that  the  provincial 
government  sector  is  expected  to  grow  faster  than  the  Ontario  economy  as  a  whole. 
Hence  even  if,  contrary  to  our  expectation,  projected  provincial  revenues  were  to 
grow  at  the  same  rate  as  expenditures,  an  increasing  burden  of  debt  would  be 
indicated. 

116.  The  second  consideration  is  that  we  have  in  fact  projected  a  relatively 
more  rapid  rate  of  growth  in  total  expenditure  than  in  total  revenue.  Every  major 
category  of  expenditure  shown,  with  the  exception  of  grants  to  municipalities  for 
capital  purposes,  increases  relatively  more  rapidly  than  total  provincial  revenue. 
While  in  most  categories  this  discrepancy  in  growth  rates  is  slight,  the  major  excep- 
tion is  to  be  found  in  the  current  expenditure  item  (exclusive  of  interest  and  of 
transfers  to  local  governments)  shown  in  line  4  of  Table  6:12.  This  is  the  largest 
single  category  of  provincial  expenditure  and  it  increases  more  than  four-fold 
during  the  period  of  our  projection.  The  major  components  which  account  for  this 
rapid  rate  of  increase  are  outlays  for  post-secondary  education,  expected  to  increase 
seven-fold,  and  those  for  health,  for  which  a  four-fold  increase  is  expected. 

117.  Finally,  increased  debt  leads  to  an  increase  in  interest  charges.  Projected 
total  interest  charges  during  the  period  are  approximately  $1,600  million,  about 
$850  million  greater  than  would  have  resulted  had  the  annual  interest  charge 
remained  at  the  1964  level  throughout  the  period.  The  additional  $850  million  in 
interest  payments  in  effect  increases  the  total  accumulated  debt  at  the  end  of  the 
period  by  the  same  amount. 

118.  In  summary,  if  present  trends  continue,  the  net  capital  debt  of  the 
Province  can  be  expected  to  increase  very  rapidly  in  the  coming  decade,  both 
absolutely  and  as  a  proportion  of  provincial  domestic  product.  In  this  context,  it  is 
relevant  to  consider  the  present  and  projected  position  of  Ontario's  debt  in  relation 
to  earlier  experience.  At  the  end  of  the  1920's,  the  burden  of  the  Province's  debt 
was  an  estimated  9  per  cent  of  P.D.P.  The  debt  increased  rapidly  during  the 
depressed  1930's,  and  by  the  end  of  that  decade  the  burden  had  grown  to  24  per 
cent  of  P.D.P.  It  may  therefore  be  observed  that  while  the  present  debt  ratio  is  at 
about  the  level  of  the  late  1920's,  the  projected  ratio  in  1975  will  have  risen  to 
the  approximate  level  of  the  late  1930's.  It  may  be  said  of  such  a  debt  ratio 
that  not  only  would  it  be  historically  very  high  in  terms  of  Ontario  experience, 
but  that  it  would  continue  to  rise  rapidly  beyond  1975,  if  present  trends  continue. 

1 19.  We  wish  to  offer  a  concluding  word  to  explain  why  we  have  chosen  to 
use  the  "net  capital  debt"  rather  than  the  "gross  debt"  of  the  Province  in  our 
analysis.  The  major  difference  between  these  concepts  is  that  the  gross  debt 
includes  "revenue-producing  and  realizable  assets"  while  net  debt  excludes  these 

202 


Chapter  6:  Paragraphs  115-120 

items.  In  measuring  burden,  net  capital  debt  seems  to  us  to  be  preferable,  but 
it  may  be  argued  that  because  the  Province  must  pay  interest  on  its  gross  debt, 
our  procedure  may  underestimate  future  interest  charges  if  the  gross  debt  increases 
faster  than  the  net  debt.  The  interest  figures  we  have  used  to  the  end  of  1967 
represent  either  the  actual  net  interest  cost  to  the  Province  or  a  very  close  estimate. 
Thereafter,  our  procedure  involves  the  assumption  that  increases  in  "revenue- 
producing  and  reahzable  assets"  will  generate  enough  income  to  pay  the  interest 
charges  to  which  such  increases  give  rise.  This  seems  a  reasonable  assumption 
which,  even  if  not  strictly  borne  out  in  fact,  is  nevertheless  most  unlikely  to 
introduce  any  significant  error  into  our  projection. 

COMBINED  PROVINCIAL  AND  LOCAL  BUDGETARY  AND  DEBT  POSITION 

120.  In  Table  6:13  we  show,  for  selected  years,  combined  revenue,  expendi- 
ture and  debt  figures  for  the  provincial  and  local  governments.  There  are  some 
technical  difficulties  about  combining  the  figures  when  the  fiscal  years  are  different 
for  the  two  levels  of  government,  but  to  discuss  this  matter  fully  would  be  both 
tedious  and  unnecessary.  Any  apparent  discrepancies  are  small  and  have  no 
effect  on  the  general  trends  revealed  in  the  Table. 

Table  6:13 

COMBINED  PROVINCIAL  AND  LOCAL  GOVERNMENT  BUDGETARY 
AND  DEBT  POSITION 

Calendar  year  or  1974 

nearest  fiscal  year  as  a 

percentage 


1963  1969         1974       of  1963 


(millions  of  dollars) 
Revenue 

1.  Current   revenue    (including   debt   service 

payments  from  universities)   1,909         3,306         4,631         243% 

Expenditure 

2.  Expenditure  on  current  account   (exclud- 

ing interest)    1,416 

3.  Interest    126 

4.  Total  Current  Account  Expenditure 1,542 

5.  Surplus  on  Current  Account 367 

6.  Expenditure  on  Capital  Account  525 

7.  Deficit  (=  increase  in  net  debt)  158 

8.  Total  Accumulated  Net  Debt  2,844 

9.  Estimated  separate  school  net  debt  133 

10.  Total  Net  Debt  less  separate  school  net  debt*  ....  2,71 1 

11.  Provincial  Domestic  Product  15,600 

12.  Debt  (line  10)  as  percentage  of  P.D.P 17.4% 


2,735 
229 

4,056 
429 

286 
340 

2,964 

342 
942 

4,485 

146 
1,318 

1,172 

291 

40 
251 

600 

742 

5,278 
190 

9,819 

247 

345 
186 

5,088 

9,572 

353 

22,200 

22.9% 

30,000 

31.9% 

192 

"Includes  $559  million  in  1969  and  $952  million  in  1974  owing  by  universities  to  Ontario 
Universities  Capital  Aid  Corporation. 


203 


Projection  of  Expenditure,  Revenue  and  Debt 

121.  The  fact  that  the  figures  in  Table  6:13  do  not  include  transfers  between 
the  two  levels  of  government  enables  us  to  see  the  total  projected  actual  cost  of 
carrying  out  various  expenditure  programs  and  the  total  revenue  available  to  finance 
these  programs.  Eliminating  the  complications  arising  from  intergovernmental 
transfers  enables  the  reader  to  come  more  closely  to  grips  with  the  fundamentals 
of  the  fiscal  position. 

122.  The  combined  provincial-local  Table  does  not  add  a  great  deal  to  the 
information  already  provided  in  Tables  6:6  and  6:12.  We  note  that  in  the 
combined  Table,  6:13,  total  revenue  rises  more  rapidly  than  P.D.P.,  but 
expenditure  in  turn  rises  more  rapidly  than  revenue.  The  rise  in  expenditure  on 
current  account  is  particularly  striking,  just  as  it  was  for  the  provincial  govern- 
ment. The  net  result  is  a  series  of  continuously  rising  annual  deficits,  augmented 
by  the  compounding  effect  of  related  interest  payments  and  reflected  in  the  very 
rapid  growth  of  accumulated  debt,  both  absolutely  and  in  relation  to  P.D.P. 
By  1974,  our  figures  show  debt  increasing  by  almost  $1,200  million  a  year;  total 
debt  is  about  3!/2  times  the  1963  level  and  the  ratio  of  debt  to  P.D.P.  will  have 
almost  doubled  over  the  period. 

123.  While  the  projected  ratio  of  debt  to  P.D.P.  in  1974  is  approximately 
that  of  1939,  the  fact  that  the  trend  continues  strongly  upward  in  subsequent 
years  indicates,  as  we  have  already  pointed  out,  that  the  projected  fiscal  position 
is  not  viable  for  the  longer  term.  To  illustrate  this  point,  we  have  developed  in 
Chapter  40  the  dimensions  of  the  annual  revenue  gaps  that  would  need  to  be 
filled,  if  the  growth  in  the  combined  provincial-local  debt  were  to  be  confined  to 
the  projected  rate  of  growth  in  the  P.D.P.  Given  such  a  policy  of  stabilizing  the 
burden  of  debt  at  its  present  ratio,  our  projection  indicates  that  the  annual  com- 
bined revenue  gap  for  the  two  levels  of  government  would  in  1969  amount  to 
almost  $400  million  and  in  1975  to  some  $800  million.  Had  we  extended  our 
projection  further  into  the  future,  there  is  every  indication  that  this  gap  would 
have  continued  to  increase. 

CONCLUSION 

124.  In  explaining  the  various  projections  developed  in  the  Appendix  and 
presented  in  this  chapter,  we  have  become  unavoidably  involved  in  much  detail. 
We  think  it  appropriate  to  conclude  this  presentation  with  some  rather  general 
observations  about  the  basic  assumptions  and  techniques  that  we  have  employed 
in  determining  and  analysing  the  evolving  fiscal  positions  of  the  provisional  and 
municipal  governments  in  Ontario  during  the  forthcoming  decade. 

125.  Central  to  our  whole  analysis  are  our  projections  of  the  population, 
labour  force  and  domestic  product  of  the  Province  of  Ontario.  We  believe  that 
these  are  the  best  projections  that  can  be  made,  but  inevitably  they  will  be 
proved  wrong  and  we  think  that  they  are  as  likely  to  be  too  high  as  too  low. 
If  our  projections  are  found,  in  the  event,  to  be  too  low,  then  actual  revenues 
at  given  rates  of  tax  will  be  higher  than  those  projected.  But  this  upward  influence 
will  also  be  felt  in  expenditure.   On  balance,  we  would  expect  that  if  actual  popula- 

204 


Chapter  6:  Paragraphs  121-128 

tion,  labour  force  and  production  are  higher  than  we  have  projected,  the  net  effect 
on  the  government's  budgets  would  tend  to  be  favourable  but  not  pronounced.  The 
opposite  conclusion  would  apply  if  our  projection  is  found  to  be  too  high. 

126.  In  our  projections  of  revenue  we  have  generally  assumed  the  continuation 
of  present  taxes  and  rates,  except  for  the  municipal  real  property  and  business 
tax  and  the  Ontario  Hospital  Services  Commission  premiums.  Assuming  that 
our  P.D.P.  projection  is  correct  (and  we  have  already  considered  the  effects  of 
possible  error),  we  think  that  our  revenue  projections  are  subject  to  no  very  large 
margin  of  error. 

127.  The  determination  of  future  trends  in  government  expenditures  is  con- 
siderably more  difficult,  but  here  again  we  have  tried  to  anchor  our  projections  as 
firmly  as  possible  to  present  conditions,  past  experience,  and  the  expected  course 
of  future  developments.  In  general,  we  have  tended  to  project  the  costs  of  existing 
government  services  in  such  a  manner  as  to  make  some  provision  for  the  introduc- 
tion of  minor  new  expenditures  during  the  period.  We  have  explicitly  excluded 
any  provision  for  the  costs  of  major  new  programs  that  are  not  now  a  part  of 
publicly  announced  government  policy. 

128.  To  sum  up,  our  projections  lead  us  to  the  clear  and  inescapable  conclu- 
sion that  in  the  absence  of  remedial  measures,  the  present  unsatisfactory  revenue 
and  spending  positions  of  the  provincial  and  local  governments  of  Ontario  will 
deteriorate  sharply  and  continuously  within  the  coming  decade.  While  we  recognize 
the  inevitability  of  errors  in  our  projections,  we  think  that  their  effect  cannot  be  to 
alter  substantially  the  fiscal  trends  that  we  foresee.  Moreover,  any  errors  that  we 
have  made  are  as  likely  to  aggravate  the  fiscal  situation  as  to  improve  it.  The 
concrete  problem  that  emerges  is  that  of  determining  the  most  appropriate  means 
of  financing  a  combined  provincial-local  expenditure-revenue  gap  which  will 
have  grown  to  some  $600  million  annually  by  1969  and  to  more  than  $1,300 
million  by  1975,  just  to  finance  existing  programs.  To  the  extent  that  major  new 
programs  are  introduced,  the  projected  gap  will  be  correspondingly  increased. 
Faced  with  such  a  prospect,  the  government  of  Ontario  may  be  expected  to  seek  a 
greater  share  of  revenue  from  what  are  now  federal  sources  of  income.  In  coping 
with  the  remaining  revenue  gap,  the  Province  will  need  to  consider  to  what  extent 
it  may  wish  to  modify  the  projected  level  of  its  public  expenditures  and  to  what 
degree  it  will  rely  on  taxation  and  on  borrowing  to  meet  its  financial  requirements. 
Given  the  terms  of  reference  of  this  Committee,  we  confine  our  analyses  and 
recommendations  to  the  areas  of  taxation  and  borrowing. 


205 


Projection  of  Expenditure,  Revenue  and  Debt 


On 


•FN 

On 


O 
H 

o 
» 

o 

H 


vo 


a, 


H 


o 

c 

e 


(L) 


X) 

c 
o 


a:. 

< 

Z 

o 

oi 
O 
bu 

H 
U 
D 
Q 
O 

U 

P 
(/I 

o 

Q 

< 

u 

z 

> 
o 

Oh 

Q 
Z 

< 
H 
Z 

u 

>- 

O 

0. 

w 

U 
oi 

o 

oi 
O 

00 

< 

z' 

O 
< 

Ou 

o 
o 

X 

^ 

O 

oi 

a 

Q 


■*  vo  -H 

>0       -^       ON 
oo"     r»C     «n" 


<0      On      00 


NO     w-i     m 

Tt         O         ON 

<N      oo      NO 


NO      <N      <N 


rj  >o  >o 

m  r~  — 

00  nO^  NO 

no'  fN  <N 


NO     rvi     fs 


a    NO     ^     m 


a   NO    <N    <si 


a   oo 
a    NO 


a 

o 
o. 


—  <o 


— '  rs 


00  — 

~  <N 


•5     >» 


•^     I 

J3    Z    £ 


o 

—  'i/T 

0.2 


F 

o 

o 
Q 

15 

w 

c 

ca 

> 

o 

o-o 

—       <N      r<^ 


"z:        x: 


60  O 

*^  > 
c  w 

E 


•5  «J    .ii 


E.y 
•o  o 


Suj 


o  > 
ii  o 


>   3 

Ji  So 


o2 

c)  c 
3.2 

(J    CO 

"Z!  C 
y— 
.«-o 

a3 

I,  <D  . 
3   S   C 

•E  «  5 

23  -  & 
O  vo  u, 

1)  t, 

5  rt  o 

""  r.  2 
*    fc«    O 

ii; 

O-rt  4> 
■"  «   3 

u  c  5o 

•S  X  to 
•5  <u    - 

H  i£  "^ 

(/I  o  u 

^  lie 
•E  u  "^ 

"t2  o- 

u-  .../■  WJ 
tfl  ^  3 
f-  C  tn 

la  3  ^ 

4»   tS 
O  C  OV 

u2 


!> 


y  ■** 

2  wvo 

0^ 

</>  On 

Oi  0 

T3   0- 

3  ^ 

964  am 
ty  in  th 
67  and 

0  w 

j2  t! 

~1  CO 

c  a 

-■>2 

0  « 

n»  ?^ 

•=Q 

a^vo 

w  -, 

0   ^ 

•B^ 

rt.yoN 
«  E^T 

a-- 

0  >, 

fSg^ 

OuJo 

206 


Chapter  6:  Appendix 


(3  OO 


U   '^ 

h-l 
< 
Oh 


:S^ 


5- 


00    Tj- 

00 

^ 

OO    <N 

s 

fN    00 
00    «N 

00  rs 

5\ 

1^ 

00 

OS 

;t 

00 

OO 

O   —1 
00 

O 
1^ 

52 

00 

M      = 

c    « 

'i  s 

S  * 

O  ^ 

t:  ,0) 

0H  u. 


e 

w 

3 
C 

oi 

u 

> 

c 

<L> 

9 

IM 

fc 

a 

2 

u 

o 

H 

jc 

m  r4 

00    f»1 


00   <N 


Tt     1/^  -H 


«->    00 
O   '^ 


00  m        — 


o 

m 

</^ 

3 

f<-i 

OV 

<N 

r4 

On 

1^ 

o 

ON 

NO 

00 

s 

OO 
OS 

OS 

so 

so 

00 

so 

>r> 

so 

i 

r^ 

5 

so 

—     so     w^ 


-o 

c 

(/) 

3 
O 

■It 

05  5. 

~-     3 

5  a 
to  <- 

^  e 

S  Z 
5 
-Si 


O 

E    5 


^  a 


>n 

so 
00 

in 

SO 

IT) 

so 
OS 

00 

■"I- 

O 

so 

OS 

so 

o\ 

OS 

O 

so 

OO 

m 
? 

OS 

00 

CO 

o 

OS 

SO 

00 

SO 

5^ 

OS 

SO 

IT) 

3 

O 
OO 

OS 

</) 


"5. 

u 

T3  ♦ 
C  (rt 

«  c 

o 


cfl  E 


c 

o   o.-r 


00 

<s. 

c 

rt 

u 

a 

3 

o 

o 

c 

"ci 

v 

u^ 

b. 

a 

3 

to 

u  u 

u 


c     ^ 


>.      «  ^ 


'5  >..?  2 


o    _« 


a 


*-  c 

>>  00 

o    O  o 


X 

5  e- 


•3-     W       «0 


>i    S   ti  — . 


E   - 


w  c 


3    cfl  ^ 

U  U 


3  <o 


207 


Projection  of  Expenditure,  Revenue  and  Debt 


a: 
D 

H 

5 
z 

Oh 

X 

uu 

< 

CU 

:::  < 

lu   Q  <A 

CD      ^    0\ 

<      <    ^ 


H 
Z 

a: 

D 
U 

< 
U 

z 

D 


«r>  r<^  r»^ 
in  T}-  00 


«N  ON  VO 

rj-  ro  m 


<S 


</^ 


^-00- 
•o    ON  <S  00 


5 

^  ON  v£>  OS 

r~  <N  ■* 


fSTtON 

NO  <N  — 


ON  <N  — 
Tj-tNON 


ONO-* 
rn  tN  NO 


<N  m  >o  m    r^ 
<N  u-i  <si  r-    r-    — 

ro  ^  in     NO 


fO  ON  »^  On 
O  <^  <S  NO 


O  00  —  Tj- 
00  <S  <N  NO 
<N  — ' 


NONOOO 
NO  —  <N  NO 


m  l~~  00  NO 
>r>  O  "  «o 


Tj-  On  >/%  ON 

—  00  -^  ■^ 


2  « 
c   o 


x: 


5  Ouio 


o 


a   - 

I  *-S^-   : 

J 


■X.    "* 

a   a 


ui 
U 

z 

> 

o 

Oh 

O 

Q 

> 

U  ,1- 

NO 

on  <^ 

Z 

< 
oi 
O 

H 

z 

UJ 

z 

UJ 

> 

O 
O 

< 

u 
o 


O  —  ON 

NO  NOrf 


O  ^  '^ 


m  «->  00 

00  «^  <N 


ON  «N  00 


00  ON  O 
— ,  Tt  — 
Tt  — 


^   OONO  <N 
Q   oo-<t  O 


-^  -^00 


00  r4  r^ 

v^ 
^ 

oor-Tt 
r~  —  rn 

•<t2or4 

r5 

VO  0  <^ 

ON 
ON 

"(ftOO 
NOOvfN 

NO 

00 

—  ON  NO 

NO  00  <N 

VO 

ON  >/^T}- 
W-)  00  <S 

00 

vO 

r-  o«N 

>O00<N 

ON 

On  «N  — 

r4 

ON  00  00 
TJ- so- 

rt —  «-! 
^NO- 

§ 

NO  r^t 

0 

^      *;       Co 


3  C   O  V- 

O  O   >    3 

<-<  (SJ    (J    t, 

S  uja.O 


c     *. 


O 


■o     •  iZ  .ti    • — 
Q   o  ^  td 

•~  -a  3  x    o   O 
5  uJOuO   h-   - 

,3^  o 


208 


Chapter  6:  Appendix 


^ 


1^ 

O 

ri 

00 

oo 
rJ 

o 

m 
rf 

OS 

CO 

ri 

o 

00 

'"' 

"■^ 

O 

ON 

m 

00^ 

"^ 

"^ 

00 

00 

O 
in 

'" 

^^ 

2 

00 

00 

^^ 

'■^ 

r- 
o 

00 

5 

'^ 

'"' 

1 

00 
CO 

OS 
00 

O 
00 

00 

ro 

(U       3 


o 


On 

rn 

v^ 

Tf 

00 

O 

so 

00 

o 

OO^ 

5 

On_^ 

^^ 

^' 

00 

^^ 

'■^ 

o 

NO_^ 

'^ 

'"' 

2 

00 

NO 

^^ 

'"' 

o 

s^ 

"^ 

'"' 

so 

00 

"^ 

^^ 

00 

oo 

SO 

^^ 

^^ 

0^ 

R 

ON 

'^ 

'"^ 

SO 

ON 

O 

C-- 
O   60 

c 


-        -S        -.  S       C4> 


^  w      a 


u 


3         t 

I  3 


UJ 


w      _      ^ 


a       s     ^     t 


so 

ON 

i 

r3 

ON 
ON 

ro 

SO 
00 

00    r~      -^ 


On 

00 

so 

ON 

m 

On 

5 

ON 

ro 

so 
so 

§ 

00 

O 

SO 

2 

so 

so 

ro 

SO 
en 

CO 

ON 

SO 

en 

S 

O 

00 

r- 
■* 

CO 

SO 

00 

ON 

ON 

2         k! 


Q<    c 


.5    5 


t 


c    o. 


U 


c    2 


5 

ON 

«N 

<N 

ON 

m 

<N 

O 

Tt 

SO 

r- 

rn 

CO 

o, 

<N 

00 

ro 

<N 

Tt 

rj 

«S 

ON 

«N 

r- 

00 

<N 

SO 

<N 

*N 

^ 

, 

O 

«N 

«-M 

t- 

<N 

«n 

rf 

<N 

ON 

Q 

ON 

Tt 

o 

•* 

w-»^ 

<S 

r-i 

ri 

«S 

o 

o 

o 

00 

o\ 

On 

r-i 

ri 

<N 

m 

o 

fO 

(N 

00 

■* 

<N 

^^ 

O^ 

(N 

ri 

O 

^^ 

On 

00 

r~- 

O 

o 

T— K 

ON_^ 

<N 

'■^ 

r^ 

<N 

_, 

m 

SO 

r- 

ON 

I-; 

^^ 

'^ 

m 

t^ 

25 

tr> 

Tf 

00__ 

F-H 

SO 

'^ 

*^ 

r- 

Tt 

m 

3, 

Ti- 

O 

^^ 

'^ 

o\ 

ro 

SO 

ON 

m 

SO 

Tt 

*-^ 

ro 

d   §  =  = 


■5       ^       T3W 


«       2    «i     eg 


a 

X 

0 

c 

'11 

3 

0 

^  c 

3__ 
0  0 
*-.  0 



^*-' 

Ji 

X)J= 

3 

■5 

T3 

F 

•0  «) 

0. 

tC 

i-> 

-M 

^     U     Q      Z   W    Z 


^ 


.3      c 
c      >^ 

'i  I 


^  '^    H 


209 


Projection  of  Expenditure,  Revenue  and  Debt 


ii 


< 
H 
Z 

o 
o 

H 
Z 

UJ 

z 

OS 

u 

>  <o 
O  ^Y 

UJ 
3C 
H 


5 
«  U,  Si 

W  j~ 
D  ^ 
Z 

> 

>- 

< 
z 

5 

O 
H 

UJ 

Z 


r~  m  vo  m  -H  OS  o\ 
m  00  00  —  o  <S  "Ti 


oooo<N>/^oooa\r4rt 
«r>    f»^    r>^    >ri  -H    --<  ts 


OCT^»NONVc>inoo<ri<N 
«^     <^     m     u->  -^     —  «N 


Ooooooo    —    r^ooTto 
O<^osoor-osc>(s»s 

V)  m  fS  "I'     —  ^^     <N 


,^ 

o 

r- 

O 

r- 

00 

00 

JS 

r~ 

oo 

v£) 

VO 

ON 

w-i 

<N 

Tt 

m 

<N 

■<t 

■— ' 

■5 


2  ■*  <^ 


^O  f*^  f*^  ■^  OS  *-■  t^ 
r~  m  so  On  ■^  fN  OS 


O  -^  <S  — < 

r-  fN  SO  OS 


lb 

*<  s 


oo 

00 

3 

O 

s 

oo 

^ 

^ 

00 

00 

oo 

so 
oo 

CO 

1^ 

so 

5 

so 

00 

OS 

1^ 

OS  ro 


3  2 


—  <A)  o\  —  f*^  "^ 
<N  OS  -"^r  00  —  t-' 


r~  OS  I  — 


♦2  <"   -^ 


o  S 


to 

5p 


5h 

< 

Q 
Z 

O  ,- 
U  §f 

H  ^ 

O  =^ 


O  -a 

8 

Z  ■^ 

o 
p 

D 
n 

q2 

H 
in 


O 

s; 

r- 

00 

SO 

tv. 

^ 

00 

tN 

Os 

^ 

•-1 

3 

o 

^ 

s 

■^ 

< 

Os 

O 

00 

<N 

^ 

1 

00 

«S 

Z 

•»( 

o 

1 

z 

a© 

•« 

^^ 

r- 

OO 

■<^ 

^ 

^ 

r- 

C/3 

hv 

""-I 

H 

"A 

z 

^ 

t*^ 

tv 

r- 

so 

Q 

so 

H 

0\      ^ 


Tt  00  00 


5 


so 

s 

oo 

§ 

r- 

O 

>o 

rj 

■<t 

o 

r^ 

so 
OS 

- 

00 

0\ 

00 

s 

r- 

-^  -^   <s 


s 

C  3  73 
3   O   c 


H  H 


O 


210 


Chapter  6:  Appendix 


o 

H 

<: 
u 

D 
Q 
U 

>H 
< 

Q 

Z 

o 
o 
u 

C/3 

H 

O 

o  ^ 

I— I  "-1 

o   S 

O   ^ 

H 
Z 

u 

Z 
oJ 
u 
> 

o 
O 
u 

33 

H 

O 
H 

en 
H 

O 
U 


o 

'^ 

^ 

^ 

"-^ 

"S 

"«3 

On 

'^ 

^ 

2 

0\ 

c 

~-^ 

.2 

J, 

00 

<) 

^8 


^**'^^ 


5 

a- 

IT) 

ON 

<N1 

<N 

2 

r~~ 

m 

1^ 

- 

o 

0^ 

00 
ON 

I^ 

00 

tn 

Tf 

5 

D   H 


o 

•o 

c 

-3.2 
c  ^ 

4>     .2    O 
60     .^   3 

—    y  W 
u    >  ^ 


U 


m    r-        v\ 


<s    -H         «o 


v^     #  -^ 


2 

i 

§ 

00 

00 

r- 

o 

r4 

00 

00 

'it 

NO 

00 
00 

o 

oo 

o 

•tJ 

c 

CS  c 

«.2 
c  -^ 
o 


3    a  .)£  <-> 

CO  X3 


8" 
>  >^ 

o  c 


U 


H    H 


/ — . 

u 

> 

o 

^ 

a 

u 

•a 

> 

U 

O 

•o 

£ 

3 

eiJ 

O     -o 


^ 


o 

</> 

L 

U 

C/3 

B 

^ 

Jo 

t^  Q 


211 


Projection  of  Expenditure,  Revenue  and  Debt 


y^ 


C/3 

UJ 

5  Z  ^ 

w  ^; 
o 

< 

H 
Z 

o 

O 

H 
Z 

UJ 

Z 

U 
> 

O 

a 


-^3  ^ 


'•< 


-  -   00 


3 

S 

r<^ 

O 

00 

■* 

- 

■* 
■* 

O 

00 

o 

OS 

0^ 

00 

r4 

oo 

VD 

o 

m 

rr, 

oo 
oo 

OS 

O 

1^ 

O 

00 

m 

o 

OS 

O 

ON 

00 

00 

0\ 
OS 

00 

00 
<N 

OS 

r- 

o 

r^ 

■* 

so 

O 

OO 
OS 

^ 

.  J[, 

■a 

•o 

c 

c 

(U 

u 

o. 

a 

X 

X 

.  w 

'^ 

u 

c 

u 

s 

2 

'a 

z 

3o 

C 

'T 

O    CJ 

?   c 


u 


CJ 

K    W 

u 

-  1) 

a 

t;  i- 

c 

cfl   i^ 

? 

e-</ 

o 

o-o 

s:    w  t  c 
,>^  .ti  *-  w 


a 


O     —    -^ 


C3     C    W    <1>       W 


3   -     .      & 
UJ 


c    -5 


C  e«  to 

*  a   - 

>  •—  oo 
O   Ot3 

c'c  « 

O  3  2 
Ji  '^  C 
3   O  ° 


—   y 


U   UJ 


H  •—  "^  a>     ^ 


Si    X  ,t         o     Si    X  ,t 

•S  WO        H    -S  wO 


(73 

UJ 
H 

ei 

O 

I— > 

< 

I 

H 

< 
UJ 

a: 

Q 

z 
< 

on 

CO    Ifl 

o  •> 


z  ^ 

O  5 

C/3     § 

W    K 

§2 

Q 
Z 

UJ 

CU 

X 

UJ 

O 
Z 

o 

u^ 

o 

H 

z 

UJ 

s 
z 

UJ 

> 

o 
o 


o     —     — 


5 


6p  a 


'-     c  •  — 

3     O   g 

S£E 


o  ^ 


.2> 


;'-5 

05! 

0  O 
c-r 

.E  c 

30 

I         I 

JS'g    4>  J 

2  cu-5  0- 
I  «  "^  2 
°E^ 


^3: 


Cl,      O      PU 


:£5 


8      5  o 


S-    to 
[^    o 


^    - 1 


"^     S    X 

a  o- 
■5.    2 


I 


UJ 


212 


Chapter  6:  Appendix 


Q 
Q 

U 

z 

H 
O 

^^ 

tU    ^ 


UJ 

X 


8 


00     o\     Tf 
00     rf     fN 


^     5 


tn 
1 

</-! 
■51- 

00 

1^ 

"J- 

vo 

'^ 

c 

<N 

_„ 

2; 

So 

5 

r^ 

"I- 

■s^ 

0 

■t 

a 

^ 

-Q 

1^ 

■^ 

1 

, , 

ON 

«N 

V~l 

j\ 

rn 

-* 

^H 

^ 

m 

1> 

a 

^ 

s: 

^ 

^-^ 

00 

NO 

ON 

s 

v-\ 

m 

s 

<N 

«j 

3, 

0 

M 

0^ 

NO 

g 

Tt 

<N 

3 

fN 

ti 

3 

■•5 


5;     uo    — >    T-i 


Sag, 


X    -^ 


k;  - 


UJ 


::  z 


=    •—       <u 


0 

in 

^ 

0 
00 

0 
1^ 

1^ 

(N 

r~- 

0 

NO 

n 

>n 

NO 

00 
Cn| 

NO 

On 
m 

§ 

NO 

NO 

1^ 

On 

s 

^ 

tT)      NO 


i:      1^ 


c 
0 

3   § 

o  <u 


g-       c^ 


2  c 

<2 

nj  c/) 

60  0 

■!2 

60£ 

>  2 

c 

03 

-^ 

S  u 

00 

■z^-a 

cQ   0. 

i2  c 

■^   0 

flj 

■^    C3 

•■=      i;      X 


a    .£ 


I—         J-" 


O       h 


H      - 


213 


Projection  of  Expenditure,  Revenue  and  Debt 


< 

H 

z 

o 

bu 
O 

H 
Z 

UJ 

Z 
> 

O 
O 

u 

X 

H 

U< 

O 

z 
o 

O 

Qu 

H 

CO 

U4 

Q 

Q 
Z 

< 

> 

< 

(- 
UJ 

O 
Q 


^     VO     -t 


6p  a 


'^ 


—         oo    r~ 


3 
C 

3 

4> 

ti 

I) 

p 

i: 

<« 

efl 

c 

c 

a> 

«  t 


5  « 


OS        —    r^ 


—    o 


Tt-      00 

OO      00 


s 


•sg, 


c  ■" 

D.TD 
!"     X   C 


O  1^ 


UJ 


<  t 

*-      3 


».  O  at 


3      " 
(J      ^ 

W5  o     i>    —    _ 


1-2   « 


ON 

ON 

00 
00 

00 
Ov 

so 

<N 

00 

O 

-a- 

OO 

r5 

OO 

1^ 

o 

<N 

<N 

VO 

00 

i 

O 

o 
5 

o 
1^ 

VO 

O 

VO 

00 

00 

Ov 

00 

O 

VO 

00 

>0 

00 

VO 
VO 

o 

3 

3  i2 


F.  E 


w 


5  i2  M 

S-  0.15 


>  S 
o  2 
00  o 

CJ 

2-5. 


^  c 

in   O 
i   3 


o  ;::: 


^    -^     <N     c^ 


VO      t~      00 


o^^ 


?8 


8 


5^       8        -H 


^8 


o    o    — 


—  -     OO 


\0^    VO 

w-T   od 


■S    "T       "1 


9-     3 


O-o 

•"   3 

So 
o  c 

C-- 

>  a 

la 

•3< 


•^     a     U 


Es 


O  —     «N 


z  <0 


O     X) 


a-   U 
o^  Z 


214 


Chapter  6:  Appendix 


Z 

o 
p 
5o 
O 

0. 

H 
PQ 
U 
Q 

Q 

i^ 

O    o^ 

Q  ": 
D  12 
«    S 

Z.   ^ 

w    § 

O     '=' 

Z   U 

< 

< 

u 

z 

> 
o 

oi 

Q 
u 
Z 
n 
S 
O 
u 


OS 

>0 

<N 

00 

rj- 

Tj- 

■*' 

O 

00 

oo 

rs 

m 

*— 4 

■<t 

rt 

<s 

rn 

«N 

m 

°°, 

rn 

■«t 

O 

OS 

<N 

<S 

"^r 

r^' 

0^ 

r<-i 

v^ 

fS 

<S 

<N 

ro 

ON 

Tl- 

fM 

SO 

»N 

ON 

«N 

n-i 

ro 

O 

<i-) 

<N 

r-~ 

(N 

<N 

«N 

OO 

«N 

tri 

<N 

rn 

<S 

so 

>ri 

<N 

<N 

Tt 

00 

Tf 

rn 

Ol 

*^ 

«N 

00 

m 

o 

r-^ 

" 

so 

r-i 

(N 

■* 

>o 

"•5  0 


S   U 


5"     ■ 
u3   <^ 


w.S    J5 


u 


so      00      «N 

w^     m     <-' 


r<i  Tf  -" 
O  O  O 
<N      «N      O 


Tj-      O      VO 

^     ^     (^ 

<S       -H       00 


•n     00     r»^ 

so      *0      OS 


— <      OS 

O     r- 

O      so 


m     o\     so 


m      oo     <r> 


00      TT 


<o     00     m 


«•       3     X) 


<    5 


<      t 

*-         3 


2>      y 


^    a5     C      iJ      tt 


:2   0 


c 
o 

3 

11 

3 

3 

■o 

^ 

< 

a 

^ 

nj 

3 

X 

O 

V3 

UJ 

p 

h- 

w 


2^8 


2      .E        nJ 


00    ;£ 


*-      „     ■— )  l> 


•^        -S       O  W 


Q    ii.-o 


Z      c-^ 


o 

o 

00 

so 

o 

^^ 

<N 

<N 

O 

o 

o 

o 

(TS 

o 

o     — 


a  o 

£3 

■n^ 

O 

Wt3 

""" 

|< 

S 

3  •  — 

0. 

^^ 

8^ 

Q 

•ti 

<u 

a. 

W 

215 


Projection  of  Expenditure,  Revenue  and  Debt 

NOTE  CONCERNING  THE  METHOD  USED  IN  PROJECTING 
PERSONAL  INCOME  TAX  REVENUE 

The  steps  involved  in  the  complex  projection  of  the  yield  from  the  personal 
income  tax  were  the  following: 

1.  Taxpayers  who  are  taxed  as  single  persons  and  those  having  married  status 
for  income  tax  purposes  are  considered  separately.  We  began  with  the  income 
distribution  for  single  taxpayers  as  compiled  in  Taxation  Statistics  for  the  1962 
taxation  year,  the  most  recent  year  for  which  data  were  available  when  these 
calculations  were  made. 

2.  The  average  income  and  the  average  tax  for  each  income  group  in  1962 
were  calculated. 

3.  We  assumed  that  the  average  income  in  each  income  class  would  rise  at  the 
same  percentage  rate  as  does  our  projected  P.D.P  per  worker  and  on  this  basis 
we  derived  projected  income  distributions  for  selected  future  years  (1965,  1968, 
1971  and  1974).  We  did  not  at  this  stage  provide  for  any  increase  in  the  number 
of  taxpayers  in  future  years. 

4.  We  calculated  the  average  tax  per  person  and  the  total  tax  in  each  year  for 
each  income  group,  on  the  assumption  that  the  1962  figures  relating  tax  to  income 
would  continue  to  apply.  In  this  way  we  derived  the  total  tax,  on  the  same  number 
of  taxpayers  as  in  1962,  for  each  of  the  selected  future  years. 

5.  A  parallel  series  of  calculations  were  made  for  married  taxpayers. 

6.  The  projected  taxes  for  the  single  and  married  taxpayers  were  added  to 
arrive  at  the  total  tax  on  the  1962  number  of  taxpayers  for  each  of  the  selected 
future  years. 

7.  It  was  assumed  that  the  number  of  taxpayers  would  increase  at  the  same 
rate  as  the  projected  number  of  persons  employed  in  Ontario.  The  tax  yield  as 
calculated  in  (6)  was  then  adjusted  by  the  appropriate  factor,  to  give  the  total 
projected  tax  revenue  in  each  of  the  selected  future  years.  The  revenue  for  inter- 
vening years  was  interpolated  from  the  projections  for  the  selected  years. 

8.  The  yield  of  the  Old  Age  Security  Tax  was  estimated  for  each  year  and 
deducted  from  the  total  tax  revenue,  since  the  revenue  to  Ontario  from  this  source 
is  calculated  on  a  base  from  which  the  Old  Age  Security  revenue  is  excluded. 

9.  Our  projections  to  this  stage  apply  to  all  Canada,  since  the  necessary  data 
on  the  distribution  of  taxable  income  for  Ontario  were  not  available,  but  it  will 
be  noted  that  we  have  assumed  that  this  total  for  Canada  grows  at  the  rate  we 
have  projected  for  Ontario.  Consequently,  we  can  determine  the  projected  tax 
revenue  for  Ontario  by  taking  the  appropriate  percentage  of  the  national  total.  In 
1962  this  figure  was  46.6  per  cent.  We  have  assumed  a  slow  decrease  in  this 
proportion  because,  since  average  income  in  Ontario  is  above  the  average  for 
Canada,  the  proportion  of  income  in  excess  of  exemptions  is  higher  for  Ontario 

216 


Chapter  6:  Appendix 

but  this  factor  will  become  less  significant  as  incomes  generally  rise  while  exemp- 
tions remain  unchanged. 

10.  We  have  assumed  that  in  1967  and  subsequent  years  Ontario  would  receive 
24  per  cent  of  the  figure  calculated  in  (9)  above  and  we  have  made  our  projection 
accordingly. 

Some  further  general  comments  concerning  this  projection  seem  appropriate. 
First,  we  have  assumed  that  the  relative  distribution  of  income  remains  unchanged 
throughout  the  period.  We  have  examined  the  effect  of  the  changes  in  income 
distribution  which  occurred  during  the  period  1953  to  1962  and  have  found  that 
the  effect  on  tax  revenues  of  such  changes  in  income  distribution  as  have  occurred 
is  negligible.  Second,  we  have  projected  an  increase  in  incomes,  implying  that  a 
higher  proportion  of  income  earners  would  be  subject  to  tax.  We  have  made  no 
allowance  for  this  entry  to  taxpayihg  status  at  the  bottom  of  the  distribution,  but 
the  revenue  accruing  from  this  source  would  be  small.  Moreover,  the  introduction 
of  the  Canada  Pension  Plan  will  increase  the  exemptions  of  many  taxpayers  and 
so  reduce  the  tax  payable  below  what  it  would  otherwise  have  been.  Neither  of 
these  factors  will  affect  revenue  by  more  than  a  small  amount  and  their  net  effect 
on  total  revenue  would  be  negligible. 

NOTE  ON  PROJECTION  AS  OF  SPRING  1967 

Our  projection  was  completed  during  the  summer  of  1966  and  we  used  the 
most  recent  figures  that  were  available  at  that  time.  For  the  Province  these  were 
provided  in  the  1966  Budget  and  in  the  1966-67  Estimates.  These  sources  provided 
final  figures  up  to  the  end  of  the  1964-65  fiscal  year,  preliminary  figures  for 
1965-66,  and  Budget  forecasts  or  Estimates  for  1966-67.  The  1967  Budget  data 
are  now  available  and  it  is  the  purpose  of  this  note  to  consider  our  projection  in 
the  light  of  these  additional  data. 

Our  primary  concern  in  this  projection  was  with  the  size  of  the  provincial 
and  municipal  debt.  In  this  note  we  are  concerned  with  the  provincial  aspects 
of  the  projection  and  so  we  shall  focus  our  comments  on  it.  In  the  1966  Budget 
data  the  net  capital  debt  of  the  Province  at  March  31,  1966,  was  estimated  at 
$1,464  million;  the  final  figure,  which  appears  in  the  1967  Budget  papers,  was 
$1,381  million  or  some  $83  million  less  than  the  preliminary  figure  of  a  year 
earlier.  This  more  favourable  result  was  caused  in  about  equal  parts  by  actual 
revenue  exceeding  the  preliminary  figure  and  by  expenditures  (both  on  current 
and  on  capital  accounts)  falling  short  of  the  1966  Budget's  preliminary  figure. 
And  these  figures  in  turn  were  a  reflection,  especially  on  the  revenue  side,  of  the 
prosperous  economic  conditions  that  prevailed  in  Ontario  in  1965  and  early  1966. 

The  general  position  is  similar  for  the  comparison  with  respect  to  the  1966-67 
figures.  The  forecast  of  the  net  capital  debt  of  the  Province  implied  in  the  1966 
Budget  papers  was  $1,546  million.  The  1967  preliminary  figure  for  the  amount 
of  this  debt  is  $1,429  million  or  $117  million  less  than  was  indicated  a  year 
earlier.    Thus  the  most  recent  estimate  of  the  debt  gives  a  figure  that  is  $117 

217 


Projection  of  Expenditure,  Revenue  and  Debt 

million  less  than  the  one  that  was  included  in  our  projection.  (It  should  be 
mentioned  that  the  debt  figure  used  in  our  projection  includes  advances  to  Ontario 
universities  by  the  Ontario  Universities  Capital  Aid  Corporation.  For  purposes 
of  this  comparison  we  have  excluded  these  advances  from  our  debt  figures  in 
order  to  make  our  figures  comparable  with  those  shown  in  the  Budget  papers.) 

For  the  1967-68  fiscal  year  our  projection  was  for  an  increase  of  $161  million 
in  the  net  capital  debt  of  the  Province;  the  1967  budget  forecast  is  for  an  increase 
of  $162.6  million.  In  this  period  both  revenue  and  expenditure  were  higher  than 
our  projection,  very  largely  because  the  federal  per-capita  grants  to  universities 
were  channelled  through  the  provincial  government  for  the  first  time,  and  the 
federal  grants  to  the  Province  were  increased  by  an  approximately  equal  amount. 

The  outcome  of  this  comparison  is  that,  while  our  projection  of  the  increase 
in  the  net  capital  debt  of  the  Province  for  1967-68  is  very  close  to  the  figure  in 
the  1967  budget,  the  accumulated  net  capital  debt  at  March  31,  1968,  now  seems 
likely  to  be  some  $115  million  below  our  projected  figure  for  that  date.  This 
should  not,  however,  cause  undue  concern.  It  is  important  in  assessing  the  increase 
in  the  debt  over  the  past  two  or  three  years  to  realize  that  this  has  been  a  period 
of  high  prosperity.  And  this  prosperity  has  been  reflected,  as  we  noted  above, 
in  the  improved  budgetary  position  of  the  Province.  It  is  virtually  certain  that 
some  time  before  1975  we  will  experience  periods  of  lesser  prosperity  than  are 
assumed  to  prevail  on  the  average  in  our  projection.  And  in  such  periods  the  net 
debt  will  rise  more  rapidly  than  has  been  allowed  for  in  our  projection.  To  put 
the  matter  somewhat  differently,  we  may  say  that  we  have  just  experienced  a 
period  of  greater  than  normal  prosperity  and  our  projection  would  be  suspect 
if  it  did  not  show  a  position  that  was  less  favourable  than  the  actual  position  at 
such  a  time. 


218 


Chapter 

7 


Recommendations 


INTRODUCTION 

1 .  The  purpose  of  this  chapter  is  to  list  all  the  recommendations  made  through- 
out this  Report.  They  are  shown  in  sequence  under  the  titles  of  the  chapters 
where  they  may  be  found.  As  their  full  import  will  not  necessarily  be  apparent 
when  read  out  of  context,  reference  should  be  made  to  the  discussion  and  reasoning 
in  the  text.  This  will  be  facilitated  by  the  applicable  chapter  and  paragraph 
numbers  that  app>ear  in  brackets  at  the  end  of  each  recommendation  in  the  list. 

FISCAL  EFFECTS  OF  THE  RECOMMENDATIONS: 
PRESCRIPTION  FOR  FUTURE  NEEDS 

1.  The  Province  raise  the  average  level  of  education  grants  to  60  per  cent  of 
school  board  expenditure  over  a  three-year  period.    (8:42) 

2.  To  the  extent  that  higher  provincial  taxation  will  be  needed  to  meet  future 
revenue  requirements,  the  Province  employ  a  carefully  balanced  combination  of 
increases  in  income,  consumption  and  wealth  taxes  designed  to  take  account  of  the 
considerations  made  explicit  in  this  Report.    (8:48) 

219 


Recommendations 

.3.  Ontario  negotiate  with  the  federal  government  for  substantial  tax  room  over 
and  above  any  abatements  that  might  be  granted  in  lieu  of  existing  shared-cost 
programs.  (8:54) 

INTRODUCTION  TO  VOLUME  II 

1.  All  local  responsibilities  for  the  administration  of  justice  related  to  the 
functioning  of  the  county  courts,  the  county  jails,  the  regional  detention  centres,  the 
registry  offices  and  the  land  titles  offices  be  transferred  to  the  Province,  and  the  local 
responsibility  for  all  other  courts  be  transferred  to  the  Province  under  arrangements 
providing  for 

(a)  appropriate  apportionment  of  the  revenue  from  fines  between  the  munici- 
palities and  the  Province,  and 

(b)  recognition  of  the  interest  of  local  public  welfare  officials  in  the  proceed- 
ings.  (9:95) 

2.  The  Province  take  steps  to  improve  the  reliability  and  comprehensiveness  of 
the  reporting  of  municipal  financial  statistics.    (9:104) 

TAXES  ON  PROPERTY:   BASIC  ISSUES  AND  POLICY  PROPOSALS 

1.  The  Assessment  Act  be  amended  to  define  real  property  liable  to  assessment 
as  being  land  and  any  building  or  other  structure  on,  over  or  under  the  land,  and 
that  for  this  purpose  a  building  or  structure  include  only  such  machinery  and  equip- 
ment as  is  a  part  thereof  and  is  used  or  required  primarily  for  the  purposes  of  the 
building  or  structure  or  to  make  it  more  habitable.    ( 1 1 :  25 ) 

2.  All  legislative  instruction  as  to  the  circumstances  affecting  value  required  to 
be  taken  into  account  in  determining  actual  value  for  assessment  purposes  be 
removed  from  the  legislation,  including  the  right  to  adopt  assessment  manuals  by 
reference.  (11:33) 

3.  The  Assessment  Act  be  amended  to  provide  that  real  property  is  to  be 
assessed  at  actual  value  without  reference  to  the  value  at  which  similar  real  prop- 
erty in  the  vicinity  is  assessed.    ( 1 1 :34) 

4.  The  assessed  value  of  each  parcel  of  real  property  be  divided  into  land 
and  structures,  and  for  this  purpose 

(a)  the  amount  attributable  to  structures  that  have  value  be  the  amount  by 
which  the  assessed  value  of  the  real  property  exceeds  the  value  of  the 
land,  and 

(b)  where  the  assessed  value  of  the  real  property  is  decreased  because  of  the 
presence  of  the  structures,  the  structures  be  determined  to  have  no  value, 
and  the  value  of  the  land  be  the  assessed  value  of  the  real  property. 
(11:48) 


The  numbers  in  brackets  following  each  recommendation  refer  to  the  chapter  and  paragraph 
where  it  is  made. 

220 


Chapter  7:  Taxes  On  Property:  Basic  Issues 

5.  The  Assessment  Act  require  that  properties  be  assessed  as  at  March  31  of 
the  year  in  which  the  assessment  roll  is  returned.    (11:51) 

6.  Legislation  be  enacted  to  enable  any  municipality  or  local  board  to  appeal 
any  provincial  assessment  equalization  to  be  used  directly  or  indirectly  in  determin- 
ing any  part  of  its  expenditures  or  revenues.    ( 1 1 :59) 

7.  The  Department  of  Municipal  Affairs  be  granted  the  right  to  appeal  any 
municipal  assessment  singly  or  any  number  of  assessments  collectively  within  any 
local  assessment  jurisdiction.    (11:61) 

8.  Where,  as  the  consequence  of  one  or  more  appeals,  a  reassessment  is  deemed 
desirable  in  the  interests  of  equity,  the  Lieutenant  Governor  in  Council  be  author- 
ized to  order  the  reassessment  on  recommendation  of  the  Minister  of  Municipal 
Affairs.   (11:63) 

9.  The  Department  of  Municipal  Affairs  be  authorized,  after  due  notice,  to 
reassess  a  municipality  at  the  municipality's  expense  where  the  local  assessment  as 
equalized  by  the  provincial  index  has  for  a  specified  number  of  years  remamed 
below  a  specified  percentage  of  actual  value.    (11:66) 

10.  The  necessary  changes  be  made  in  municipal  and  school  legislation  to 
require  mill  rates  for  commercial  and  industrial  taxpayers  to  be  uniform  with  those 
for  residential  and  farm  taxpayers.    ( 1 1 :  82) 

11.  From  the  taxable  assessment  of  residential  property,  there  be  allowed  a 
basic  shelter  exemption  in  respect  of  each  self-contained  dwelling  unit  of 

(a)  $2,000  multiplied  by  the  provincial  equalization  factor  for  the  municipal- 
ity, or 

(b)  50  per  cent  of  the  residential  taxable  assessment  applicable  to  the  self- 
contained  dwelling  unit, 

whichever  is  the  lesser.   (11:119) 

12.  The  Assessment  Act  define  business  properties  and  occupancy  for  business 
purposes.    (11:140) 

13.  (a)  The  provisions  of  The  Assessment  Act  requiring  the  actual  value  of 

farm  lands  and  buildings  to  be  determined  on  a  special  basis  be 
repealed;  and 
(b)  The  provisions  of  The  Assessment  Act  and  The  Police  Act  providing 
for  exemption  of  farm  lands  and  taxation  for  certain  expenditures  be 
repealed.   (11:188) 

14.  The  assessment  of  the  land  and  structures  of  a  farm  property  be  separated 
into  working  farm  assessment,  and  residential  assessment,  and 

(a)  the  farm  dwelling  and  the  other  parts  of  the  farm  holding  not  quaUfying 
as  working  farm  be  classified  as  residential  property; 

(b)  where  part  of  a  farm  property  does  not  qualify  as  working  farm  because 
it  is  not  fully  utilized,  only  that  portion  of  the  farm  lands  and  structures 
that  is  reasonable  in  the  circumstances  be  classified  as  working  farm;  and 

221 


Recommendations 

(c)   the  onus  be  upon  the  farm  owner  to  establish  the  extent  to  which  a  farm 
property  should  be  classified  as  working  farm.   ( 11 :201 ) 

15.  Suitable  definitions  of  "farm"  and  "working  farm"  be  enacted  in  The 
Assessment  Act.   (11: 207 ) 

16.  (a)  All  real  property,  whether  taxable  or  not,  be  assessed  each  year  at 

100  per  cent  of  actual  current  value; 

(b)  Residential  properties,  recreational  properties  and  wasteland  be 
subject  to  property  tax  on  a  taxable  assessment  of  70  per  cent  of 
assessed  value; 

(c)  Business  properties  other  than  transportation  and  communications 
properties,  but  including  working  farms  and  taxable  mining  properties, 
be  subject  to  property  tax  on  a  taxable  assessment  of  50  per  cent  of 
the  assessed  value; 

(d)  Occupants  of  business  properties  other  than  working  farms  and  trans- 
portation and  communications  properties,  but  including  taxable  min- 
ing properties,  be  subject  to  business  occupancy  tax  on  a  taxable 
assessment  of  50  per  cent  of  the  assessed  value  of  the  occupied 
property  at  the  same  mill  rate  as  the  property  tax;  and 

(e)  Roadways  and  rights-of-way  over  land  used  by  transportation  and 
communications  businesses  be  exempt  from  property  and  business 
occupancy  taxes,  and  other  properties  of  such  businesses  be  subject  to 
property  tax  and  the  occupants  thereof  be  subject  to  business 
occupancy  tax  on  a  basis  to  be  determined  when  the  assessment  of 
the  properties  has  been  completed.  (11:208) 

17.  (a)  The  legislative  provisions  for  single-  or  multi-purpose  urban  service 

areas  be  consolidated  and  made  applicable  on  a  uniform  basis  to  all 
local  municipalities; 

(b)  A  municipality  be  required 

(i)  to  give  its  taxpayers  three  weeks'  notice  of  its  intention  to  establish 
or  alter  the  boundaries  or  the  services  provided  by  an  urban 
service  area,  and 

(ii)  to  provide  an  opportunity  for  delegations  to  be  heard  by  council 
before  introducing  or  amending  its  local  by-law;  and 

(c)  Each  urban  service  by-law  or  amendment  require  the  approval  of  the 
Ontario  Municipal  Board  to  be  granted,  and  if  in  the  opinion  of  the 
Board  a  sufficient  objection  to  the  by-law  has  been  filed  with  the 
Board,  only  after  a  public  hearing.  (11:218) 


The  numbers  in  brackets  following  each  recommendation  refer  to  the  chapter  and  paragraph 
where  it  is  made. 

222 


Chapter  7:  Taxes  On  Property:  Exemptions 
TAXES  ON  PROPERTY:   EXEMPTIONS 

1.  The  Province  make  payments  in  lieu  of  school  taxes  on  its  properties,  in 
addition  to  those  now  made  in  lieu  of  municipal  taxes,  and  to  the  extent  that  they 
apply  to  elementary  schools,  such  payments,  as  well  as  those  now  made  by  the 
Hydro-Electric  Power  Commission  of  Ontario,  be  computed  at  the  lower  of  the 
public  or  separate  school  mill  rate  applicable  where  each  property  is  situated 
and  be  distributed  to  the  school  boards  on  the  basis  of  pupil  enrolment.  (12:47) 

2.  A  municipality  be  given  a  right  of  appeal  to  the  Ontario  Municipal  Board 
respecting  the  terms  of  any  agreement  made  with  the  Minister  of  Lands  and  Forests 
in  regard  to  the  financing  of  an  access  road  to  a  tax-exempt  provincial  park. 
(12:67) 

3.  The  Province  and  all  its  agencies,  and  the  Hydro-Electric  Power  Commis- 
sion of  Ontario  undertake  to  make  full  payments  in  lieu  of  municipal,  school,  busi- 
ness occupancy  and  local  improvement  levies  on  their  properties  other  than 

(a)  public  highways, 

(b)  land  betterment  works,  to  the  extent  that  they  convey  an  unrestricted 
community  benefit, 

(c)  recognized  historic  sites  that  are  not  being  exploited  commercially,  and 
monuments  or  memorials,  except  to  the  extent  of  their  utilitarian  value, 
and 

(d)  remote  or  undeveloped  Crown  lands  not  under  lease  or  subject  to  mining 
or  timber  rights  and  not  benefiting  from  local  government  services, 

except  to  the  extent  that  such  payments  are  reduced  in  recognition  of  local  services 
provided  by  the  owner  of  the  property  upon  agreement  with  the  local  authorities, 
who  shall  have  a  right  of  appeal  to  the  Ontario  Municipal  Board  as  to  the  amount 
of  any  such  reduction.   ( 1 2 :  72 ) 

4.  Privately  and  municipally  owned  recognized  historic  sites  that  are  not  being 
exploited  commercially  be  subject  to  taxation  or  payments  in  lieu  of  taxes  only  to 
the  extent  of  their  utilitarian  values.    (12:73) 

5.  Local  authorities  be  permitted  to  enter  into  agreements  with  property 
owners  for  reductions  in  their  taxes  based  upon  their  undertaking  to  provide  all 
or  some  of  their  own  local  services,  subject  to  review  by  the  Ontario  Municipal 
Board.  (12:73) 

6.  After  introducing  a  system  of  full  payments  in  lieu  of  taxes  on  provincial  and 
Hydro  properties,  the  Province  petition  the  federal  government  to  extend  its  system 
of  grants  in  lieu  of  taxes  on  federal  properties,  including  the  properties  of  Crown 
corporations  and  agencies,  to  parallel  the  basis  of  payments  in  lieu  of  taxes  on 
provincial  properties,  subject  to: 

(a)  retention  of  the  exemption  of  Indian  reserves; 

(b)  federal  decision  respecting  the  precise  basis  of  grants  for  school  purposes; 

(c)  continuation  of  the  present  method  of  assessing  federal  properties  for 
grants  in  lieu  of  taxes;  and 

223 


Recommendations 

(d)  continuation  of  the  referral  of  all  matters  relating  to  federal  grants  in  lieu 
of  taxes  to  the  Minister  of  Finance  for  final  determination.    (12:88) 

7.  (a)  Local  government  property  occupied  for  purposes  of  a  business  enter- 

prise be  taxable  on  the  same  basis  as  private  business  property;  and 

(b)  Full  taxes,  excluding  levies  for  county,  metropolitan  or  other  secon- 
tier  requisitions,  be  payable  to  local  municipalities  and  to  school  boards 
on  all  other  properties  of 
(i)   an  upper-tier  municipality, 

(ii)   a  local  authority  whose  territorial  jurisdiction  overlaps  local  muni- 
cipal boundaries, 
(iii)   a  local  municipality  situated  outside  its  boundaries,  or 
(iv)   a  local  board  situated  outside  the  municipality  where  it  exercises 
jurisdiction.  (12:102) 

8.  The  same  partial  or  full  exemption  from  payments  in  lieu  of  taxes  as  those 
recommended  for  provincial  properties  be  extended  to  local  government  proi>erties. 
(12:103) 

9.  All  present  exemptions  from  property  taxation  to  institutions  of  higher 
learning  be  terminated  following  provincial  review  of  the  merits  of  each  institution 
for  continuing  financial  assistance;  and  provincial  grant  support  to  institutions  of 
higher  learning  in  lieu  of  the  tax  exemptions  be  confined  to  those  institutions  recog- 
nized for  the  purpose  either  by  the  Department  of  University  Affairs  or  the  Depart- 
ment of  Education .    (12:112) 

10.  All  present  exemptions  from  property  taxation  to  private  schools  be 
terminated  following  provincial  review  of  the  merits  of  each  school  for  continuing 
financial  assistance;  and  provincial  grant  support  to  private  schools  in  lieu  of  tax 
exemptions  be  confined  to  schools  providing  approved  education  at  the  elementary 
or  secondary  levels.    (12:114) 

11.  Public  hospitals  be  made  subject  to  full  realty  taxes  and,  where  applicable, 
local  business  taxes;  and 

(a)  public  hospitals  be  authorized  to  include  pertinent  realty  and  business  taxes 
as  part  of  their  costs  under  the  Hospital  Care  Insurance  Plan; 

(b)  the  Province  undertake  to  pay  in  full  the  realty  and  business  taxes  charge- 
able to  the  Hospital  Care  Insurance  Plan  and  negotiate  with  the  federal 
government  to  share  the  cost;  and 

(c)  the  Province  give  consideration  to  granting  further  support  to  each  public 
hospital  in  respect  of  local  taxes  that  would  not  be  chargeable  to  the 
Hospital  Care  Insurance  Plan,  and  from  which  it  is  now  exempt,  before  the 
exemption  is  terminated.    (12:117) 


The  numbers  in  brackets  following  each  recommendation  refer  to  the  chapter  and  paragraph 
where  it  is  made. 

224 


Chapter  7:  Taxes  on  Property:  Exemptions 

12.  The  Assessment  Branch  of  the  Department  of  Municipal  Affairs  be  author- 
ized to  assess  institutions  of  higher  learning,  private  schools  and  public  hospitals  on 
which  the  Province  makes  grants  in  lieu  of  realty  or  business  taxes,  and  such 
assessments  be  subject  to  appeal.    (12:118) 

13.  Places  of  worship  and  land  used  in  connection  therewith,  and  reHgious 
seminaries  not  classed  as  institutions  of  higher  learning  or  as  private  schools,  be 
reassessed  at  actual  value  and  taxed  on  a  taxable  assessment  of  5  per  cent  of  actual 
value  in  the  first  year  and  10  per  cent  in  the  second  year,  with  increases  of  5  per- 
centage points  each  succeeding  year  until  a  level  of  35  per  cent,  or  such  other 
maximum  percentage  as  a  review  of  the  tax  position  of  places  of  worship  made 
after  five  years  may  indicate  to  be  appropriate,  has  been  reached.   (12: 127) 

14.  Present  cemetery  lands  remain  exempt  while  they  comply  with  the  terms  of 
their  existing  exemption  except  when  classified  as  adaptable  to  an  alternative  use, 
in  which  event  they  become  taxable  on  a  change  of  use  or  at  the  end  of  three  years, 
whichever  is  earlier;  and  newly  designated  cemetery  lands  be  taxable.    (12:132) 

15.  All  present  exemptions  from  property  taxation  to  charitable  organizations, 
social  and  community  service  groups  and  similar  bodies  be  terminated  following 
review  by  the  appropriate  governmental  authorities  of  the  merits  of  each  organiza- 
tion for  continuing  financial  assistance;  and 

(a)  legislation  be  enacted  to  permit  each  municipality  to  make  annual  grants 
to  charitable  organizations,  institutions,  associations  and  others  engaged  in 
works  that,  in  the  opinion  of  the  council,  are  for  the  general  advantage  of 
the  inhabitants  of  the  area;  and 

(b)  the  taxes  on  a  formerly  exempt  property  be  limited,  after  deduction  of 
any  governmental  grants-in-lieu,  to  one-third  of  the  property  and  business 
taxes  or  $100,  whichever  is  the  greater,  in  the  first  year  and  to  double 
that  amount  in  the  second  year.    ( 12: 143) 

16.  The  exemption  contained  in  The  Assessment  Act  of  up  to  twenty  acres  of 
a  farm  used  for  forestry  purposes,  and  the  authority  given  in  The  Trees  Act  for  a 
township  council  to  exempt  from  taxation  lands  under  reforestation  by  agreement, 
both  be  revoked.   (12:152) 

17.  No  further  fixed  assessments  or  fixed  taxation  agreements  be  authorized 
by  either  public  or  private  legislation,  and  steps  be  taken  to  reconcile  existing  fixed 
assessments  or  taxes  with  the  need  for  reassessment  throughout  Ontario  at  market 
value.   (12:166) 

18.  The  proposed  legislation  respecting  business  assessment  provide  that  all 
property  used  in  common  by  business  tenants  and  their  customers  be  subject  to 
business  assessment  against  either  the  owner  or  the  tenants.    ( 12: 168) 

19.  The  exemption  from  business  assessment  of  subordinate  lodges  of  regis- 
tered friendly  societies  be  revoked.    (12:173) 

20.  Municipalities  be  permitted  to   pass   by-laws   exempting   from   business 

225 


Recommendations 

assessment  land  set  aside  for  free  employee  parking  for  a  five-year  period,  and  be 
permitted  to  renew  such  exemptions  by  by-law  for  further  periods  of  five  years. 
(12:174) 

21.  The  present  formula  for  the  computation  of  provincial  payments  to  mining 
municipalities  under  The  Assessment  Act  be  replaced  by  a  formula  under  which 

(a)  the  payment  is  computed  by  applying  the  municipality's  mill  rate  for  the 
immediately  preceding  year  to  a  "municipal  mines  assessment"; 

(b)  the  "municipal  mines  assessment"  of  the  municipality  is  computed  as  that 
proportion  of  its  "fiscal  impairment"  that  the  number  of  its  mining 
employees  resident  in  the  municipality  bears  to  the  number  of  all  employed 
persons  resident  in  the  municipality;  and 

(c)  the  "fiscal  impairment"  of  a  municipality  is  computed  as  the  amount 
needed  to  make  the  ratio  of  its  commercial  and  industrial  assessment 
to  total  assessment  equal  to  that  same  ratio  for  similarly  situated  non- 
mining  municipalities.  (12:209) 

22.  Upon  adoption  of  the  proposed  formula  for  computing  provincial  payments 
to  mining  municipalities,  the  present  limitation  in  the  payment  to  a  municipaUty,  to 
50  per  cent  of  the  total  amount  that  would  have  been  levied  in  the  preceding  year 
if  no  mining  payment  for  that  year  had  been  received,  be  abolished.    (12:210) 

23.  The  present  provision  permitting  the  Minister  of  Municipal  Affairs  to 
increase  the  payment  to  a  mining  municipality  where  it  would  otherwise  be  less  than 
the  amount  of  the  tax  on  mining  profits  that  it  would  have  collected  under  The 
Assessment  Act  if  it  were  not  designated  a  mining  municipality,  be  repealed. 
(12:211) 

24.  If  the  payment  to  a  mining  municipality  within  five  years  from  the  imple- 
mentation of  the  proposed  formula  would  otherwise  be  less  than  the  amount  paid  in 
the  last  year  for  which  the  present  formula  was  applicable, 

(a)  the  amount  payable  for  the  first  year  on  the  new  formula  be  equal  to  the 
payment  for  the  last  year  under  the  old  formula  as  adjusted  for  any 
subsequent  decrease  in  mill  rate,  and 

(b)  the  amount  payable  for  the  second,  third,  fourth  or  fifth  year  on  the  new 
formula  be  reduced  by  not  more  than  the  applicable  one  of  the  following 
percentages  of  the  difference  between  the  amount  otherwise  payable  for 
the  year  and  the  amount  paid  in  the  last  year  under  the  old  formula  as 
adjusted  for  any  subsequent  decrease  in  mill  rate: 

(i)   for  the  second  year,  20  per  cent, 
(ii)  for  the  third  year,  40  per  cent, 
(iii)   for  the  fourth  year,  60  per  cent,  and 
(iv)   for  the  fifth  year,  80  per  cent. 

(12:220) 


The  numbers  in  brackets  following  each  recommendation  refer  to  the  chapter  and  paragraph 
where  it  is  made. 

226 


Chapter  7:  Taxes  On  Property:  Exemptions 

25.  The  present  provision,  under  which  the  payment  to  a  mining  municipality 
may  be  increased  to  the  amount  paid  in  the  preceding  year,  be  changed  to  provide 
that: 

(a)  a  payment  for  a  year  that  otherwise  would  be  less  than  the  payment  for 
the  preceding  year  be  not  less  than  the  proportion  of  the  preceding  year's 
payment  that  the  average  number  of  resident  mining  employees  for  the 
three  years  ending  with  the  year  of  payment  bears  to  the  average  number 
of  resident  mining  employees  for  the  three  years  ending  with  the  year 
preceding  the  year  of  payment; 

(b)  for  the  purpose  of  the  above,  where  the  payment  for  the  preceding  year 
had  been  increased  in  accordance  with  the  transitional  provision  previously 
recommended,  the  payment  for  that  year  be  deemed  to  be  the  payment 
that  would  have  been  made  if  it  had  not  been  so  increased;  and  where 
the  mill  rate  used  in  computing  the  payment  for  the  year  is  less  than 
than  that  used  in  computing  the  payment  for  the  preceding  year,  the  pay- 
ment for  the  preceding  year  be  deemed  to  be  the  amount  that  it  would 
have  been  if  the  current  mill  rate  had  been  applicable;  and 

(c)  where  under  the  transitional  provision  previously  reconmiended,  the  pay- 
ment to  the  municipality  would  be  greater  than  that  under  the  above  pro- 
vision, the  greater  amount  be  paid  to  the  municipality.    (12:220) 

26.  The  provincial  authorities  assess  the  value  of  all  mining  structures  exempt 
from  property  and  business  taxes  imposed  by  municipalities  and  school  boards. 
(12:232) 

27.  The  present  provision  in  The  Assessment  Act  exempting  "buildings,  plant 
and  machinery  in,  on  or  under  mineral  land,  and  used  mainly  for  obtaining  minerals 
from  the  ground,  or  storing  the  same,  and  concentrators  and  sampling  plant"  be 
amended  so  as  to  indicate  clearly  the  properties  that  are  exempt  and  those  that 
are  taxable.   (12:234) 

TAXES  ON  PROPERTY:   ASSESSMENT 

1.  Assessment  legislation  now  contained  in  The  Local  Roads  Boards  Act  and 
The  Provincial  Land  Tax  Act  be  transferred  to  The  Assessment  Act  and  made 
uniform  insofar  as  p>ossible  with  the  corresponding  provisions  of  that  Act;  and 

(a)  in  a  district  where  a  district  assessor  has  been  appointed,  responsibility 
for  assessing  in  a  local  roads  area  be  assigned  to  the  district  assessor, 

(b)  responsibility  for  assessing  for  provincial  land  tax  purposes  be  assigned 
to  the  Assessment  Branch  of  the  Department  of  Municipal  Affairs,  and 

(c)  the  required  level  of  taxation  within  each  provincial  land  tax  region  be 
calculated  annually  with  due  regard  for  the  Province's  cost  of  providing 
that  region  with  services  ordinarily  provided  by  local  government.  (13:45) 

2.  Real  property  used  for  transportation  or  communications  enterprises  be 
assessable  on  the  same  basis  as  other  real  property;  and 

227 


Recommendations 

(a)  the  responsibility  for  assessing  the  properties  of  transportation  and  com- 
munications enterprises  that  overlap  local  assessment  jurisdictions  be 
assigned  to  the  Assessment  Branch  of  the  Department  of  Municipal 
Affairs,  and  assessments  of  such  properties  be  subject  to  appeal  by  the 
local  taxing  jurisdictions  within  which  they  are  situated,  and 

(b)  the  Assessment  Branch  be  empowered 

(i)   to  assess  other  transportation  and  communications  properties  at  the 
request  of  the  responsible  local  jurisdictions,  and 

(ii)  to  relinquish  to  local  jurisdictions  the  responsibility  for  assessing 
transportation  and  communications  properties  where  the  extent  of 
overlapping  jurisdiction  is  nominal.    (13:84) 

3.  The  Assessment  Branch  of  the  Department  of  Municipal  Affairs  develop  and 
promote  the  adoption  of  a  plan  of  annual  reassessment  in  each  municipal  assess- 
ment jurisdiction.    (13:135) 

4.  The  Province  make  arrangements  to  ensure  that  pertinent  real  property 
information  obtained  by  other  municipal  departments  and  local  boards,  and  through 
electrical  inspections  by  the  Hydro-Electric  Power  Commission  of  Ontario,  is  made 
available  on  a  regular  basis  to  municipal  assessment  departments.    (13:135) 

5.  County  assessment  equalization  be  replaced  immediately  by  provincial 
assessment  equalization.    (13:143) 

6.  Provincial  equalization  reports  show  separate  index  figures  for  each  local 
municipality  and  for  each  major  property  classification  within  the  municipality 
and  denote  the  number  of  properties  used  in  computing  each  index.  (13:147) 

7.  The  Assessment  Branch  publicize  the  effect  upon  mill  rates  of  each  muni- 
cipal reassessment  at  present  value.   (13:163) 

8.  The  costs  incurred  by  a  municipality  in  completing  an  initial  reassessment 
at  market  value  be  reimbursed  by  the  Province  to  the  extent  of 

(a)  all  of  the  extraordinary  costs,  or 

(b)  50  per  cent  of  the  total  costs, 
whichever  is  the  greater.    (13:168) 

TAXES  ON  PROPERTY:   COLLECTIONS 

1.  The  fiscal  year  of  municipalities,  school  boards  and  other  local  boards  end 
on  March  31  of  each  year.  (14:21) 

2.  Statutory  provision  be  made : 


The  numbers  in  brackets  following  each  recommendation  refer  to  the  chapter  and  paragraph 
where  it  is  made. 

228 


Chapter  7:  Taxes  on  Property:  Collections 

(a)  requiring  local  municipalities  and  school  boards  to  adopt  their  annual 
estimates  and  strike  their  tax  rates  by  March  31  of  each  year; 

(b)  setting  appropriate  earlier  dates  for  completion  of  the  county  and  metro- 
politan estimates  and  for  submission  of  the  estimates  of  other  local  boards 
and  commissions;  and 

(c)  subjecting  the  local  authorities  concerned  to  appropriate  penalties  for 
non-compliance.  (14:22) 

3.  The  Province  encourage  expanded  use  of  instalment  tax  billing  with  a  view 
to  the  eventual  establishment  of  a  mandatory  province-wide  instalment  system. 
(14:47) 

4.  Councils  and  school  boards  be  authorized  to  fix  interest  on  overdue  taxes 
in  respect  of  the  current  or  previous  years  at  a  rate  not  less  than  6  per  cent  per 
annum  compounded  semi-annually.  (14:58) 

5.  The  owner  of  a  business  property  be  made  responsible  for  the  collection 
and  remittance  of  municipal  and  school  taxes  levied  in  respect  of  business  assess- 
ments on  his  tenants,  and  be  made  liable  for  such  taxes  that  he  fails  to  collect;  and 
the  business  property  be  subject  to  lien  for  any  such  taxes  that  are  not  paid. 
(14:67) 

6.  The  present  provisions  for  collection  of  overdue  taxes  by  county  treasurers 
be  replaced  by  new  arrangements  under  which  local  municipalities  or  school  boards 
may  contract  with  the  county  for  the  use  of  its  office  services  in  collection  of  their 
current  and  past  due  taxes.   (14:72) 

7.  The  tax  sale  procedures  of  The  Assessment  Act  be  abolished  and  replaced 
for  all  municipalities  by  the  tax  arrears  certificate  registration  system  now  provided 
in  The  Department  of  Municipal  Affairs  Act.    (14:82) 

8.  Transfer  of  title  to  a  municipality  under  a  tax  arrears  certificate  take  effect 
and  be  made  final  one  year  from  the  date  of  registration.    (14:83) 

9.  By-laws  cancelling  any  taxes  as  uncollectible  be  given  readings  at  two 
regular  meetings  at  least  14  days  apart.    (14:86) 

10.  Any  large  units  of  local  government  that  may  be  formed  in  the  future  be 
given  the  responsibility  for  administration  of  billing  and  collection  of  its  own 
taxes  and  those  of  the  municipalities  and  school  boards  within  their  territories. 
(14:89) 

SPECIAL  CAPITAL  LEVIES  AND  DEVELOPER  CHARGES 

1.  The  legislative  authority  for  financing  capital  works  through  special  levies 
be  consolidated  in  a  single  statute,  and  the  procedures  be  simplified  and  made  as 
uniform  as  possible.  (15:50) 

2.  Both  the  municipal  council  and  the  taxpayers  concerned  be  given  the  right 
of  initiative  for  all  kinds  of  capital  levy  projects.  (15:52) 

229 


Recommendations 

3.  Whenever  a  council  initiates  a  special  capital  levy  project,  a  sufficient 
opportunity  be  provided  for  the  affected  taxpayers  to  petition  against  the  work  and 
the  council  be  required  to  reconsider  the  project  if  a  petition  meeting  statutory 
requirements  has  been  lodged  against  it.  ( 15 :52) 

4.  Of  all  classes  of  property,  only  transportation  and  communications  prop- 
erties, such  as  pipe  lines,  railway  lines,  and  telephone  and  telegraph  lines,  be 
exempt  from  a  special  capital  levy,  but  such  exemption  not  apply  to  those  particular 
properties  that  will  be  benefited  by  the  project  for  which  the  levy  is  to  be  made. 
(15:53) 

5.  Provincial  legislation  classify  the  municipal  capital  works  eligible  for  financ- 
ing by  special  capital  levies  and  specify  the  form  of  levy  for  each  category  that  will 
achieve  the  most  equitable  apportionment  of  the  cost.  (15:56) 

6.  Provincial  legislation  require  each  municipality  proposing  to  use  special 
capital  levies  to  pass  a  special  assessment  by-law  which  defines  both  the  intended 
use  to  be  made  of  the  levies  and  the  proportion  of  the  total  cost  of  each  category 
of  works  that  is  to  be  financed  by  them.  (15:57) 

7.  Provincial  legislation  set  precise  limits  within  which  the  terms  of  sub- 
division agreements  may  be  drawn,  and  require  the  filing  of  such  agreements  with 
each  proposed  plan  of  subdivision  so  that  the  Province  may  satisfy  itself  that  the 
terms  of  each  agreement  are  within  the  law.  (15:90) 

8.  Cash  imposts  on  developers  for  unspecified  purposes,  or  for  purposes  other 
than  the  recovery  of  the  cost  of  allowable  municipal  service  installations  or  exten- 
sions, be  prohibited.  (15:91) 

9.  The  imposition  by  a  municipality  of  conditions  for  land  development  relating 
to  the  per-capita  assessed  value  of  subdivision  property  and  proportions  of  resi- 
dential, commercial  and  industrial  assessment,  other  than  those  provided  in  its 
planning,  zoning  and  similar  land-use  by-laws,  be  prohibited.  (15:92) 


THE  POLL  TAX 

1.  The  right  of  Ontario  municipalities  to  levy  poll  tax  be  repealed.  (16:18) 

LOCAL  NON-TAX  REVENUES 

1 .  The  Department  of  Municipal  Aff^airs  review  the  legislation  enabling  munici- 
palities to  license  or  issue  permits  for  a  fee  with  the  object  of  ensuring  that  the 
purpose  of  the  licensing  is  regulatory  rather  than  the  raising  of  revenue.  (17:16) 

2.  The  provisions  relating  to  licence  and  permit  fees  in  The  Municipal  Act  and 
other  Acts  be  amended  to  provide  that  the  amount  of  the  fee  must  not  exceed 


The  numbers  in  brackets  following  each  recommendation  refer  to  the  chapter  and  paragraph 
where  it  is  made. 

230 


Chapter  7:  Local  Non-Tax  Revenues 

the  estimated  amount  required  for  full  cost  recovery  by  more  than  approximately 
20  per  cent  or  drop  below  the  amount  required  to  produce  approximately  80  per 
cent  of  full  cost  recovery.  (17:21) 

3.  Differences  in  the  fees  charged  residents  and  non-residents  for  business 
licences  be  no  more  than  is  warranted  by  actual  differences  in  the  costs  of  regulation 
and  supervision.  ( 1 7 :  22 ) 

4.  Municipal  licensing  that  is  designed  to  limit  the  number  of  participants  in 
particular  businesses  be  prohibited  except  where  the  provincial  government  con- 
siders it  to  be  justifiable,  in  which  event 

(a)  it  be  brought  under  close  provincial  supervision,  and 

(b)  the  fees  be  set  at  levels  that  will  return  a  significant  portion  of  any 
monopolistic  profits  to  the  local  public  treasury.  (17:24) 

5.  The  Department  of  Municipal  Affairs  assist  municipalities  in  organizing 
their  accounts  so  as  to  establish  the  cost  of  goods  and  services  to  which  user  charges 
apply,  and  in  developing  appropriate  cost  recovery  policies.   (17:30) 

6.  The  Department  of  Municipal  Affairs  amend  the  form  of  municipal  audited 
financial  statements  and  its  Annual  Report  of  Municipal  Statistics  so  that  revenues 
from  user  charges  are  reported  as  revenues  rather  than  as  undisclosed  deductions 
from  related  expenditures.  (17:30) 

7.  The  Department  of  Municipal  Affairs  collect  and  publish  comprehensive 
financial  data  relating  to  all  municipal  revenue-earning  enterprises.  (17:43) 

8.  The  Department  of  Municipal  Affairs  define  "municipal  revenue-earning 
enterprises"  and  require  separate  fund  accounting  of  their  operations  whether  or  not 
they  come  under  the  immediate  control  of  some  special-purpose  body.  (17:44) 

9.  Necessary  legislative  action  be  taken  to  ensure  that  all  municipal  revenue- 
earning  enterprises  pay  full  taxes,  including  business  taxes,  and  that  they  charge 
for  all  services  provided  by  them  including  services  supplied  to  parent  municipaUties. 
(17:46) 

10.  Any  substantial  subsidization  of  municipal  revenue-earning  enterprises 
from  the  municipal  treasury,  and  retention  by  or  transfer  to  the  municipal  treasuries 
of  substantial  surpluses  earned  by  municipal  revenue-earning  enterprises,  require 
annual  authorization  by  by-law.   (17:53) 

11.  The  Department  of  Municipal  Affairs  undertake  comprehensive  studies 
designed  to  evolve  precise  and  constructive  policies  to  guide  the  operation  of  local 
revenue-earning  enterprises  with  particular  reference  to  the  form  and  extent  of 
their  revenues.  (17:54) 

LOCAL  REVENUE  AND  PROPERTY  ASSESSMENT  APPEALS 

1.  (a)  The  present  Courts  of  Revision  be  replaced  by  one  or  more  Assess- 
ment Appeal  Boards  for  each  city,  separated  town  and  county  or  any 
combination  thereof,  or  any  larger  taxing  unit  that  may  be  formed, 

231 


Recommendations 

composed  of  three  members  to  be  appointed  for  a  three-year  term  and 
remunerated  by  the  municipality; 

(b)  Similar  Assessment  Appeal  Boards  be  appointed  for  each  district  by 
the  Minister  of  Municipal  Affairs  upon  the  recommendation  of  the 
local  municipalities  within  the  district;  and 

(c)  The  members  of  an  Assessment  Appeal  Board  be  persons  meeting 
prescribed  qualifications  who  are,  or  in  the  year  prior  to  their  term 
of  office  were,  neither  employees  nor  members  of  the  Council  of  the 
municipality  or  of  the  Council  of  any  other  local  elective  body  with 
jurisdiction  within  that  municipality.  (18:12) 

2.  A  taxpayer  who  has  filed  a  notice  of  appeal  to  an  assessment  have  the 
statutory  right  to  examine,  personally  or  through  an  agent,  all  the  material  used 
to  establish  the  assessment  subject  to  objection.  (18:13) 

3.  Provision  be  made  so  that,  if  the  work  of  the  Assessment  Appeal  Board  of 
a  municipality  cannot  be  processed  within  the  statutory  time,  the  municipality  may 
appoint  a  temporary  Board  or  enlist  the  services  of  a  Board  from  another 
municipality.  (18:14) 

4.  Jurisdiction  in  all  matters  in  dispute  relating  to  municipal  property  and  busi- 
ness tax  arising  from  any  assessment,  levy  or  administrative  act  and  from  any 
decision  of  the  Assessment  Appeal  Board  be  given  to  the  County  or  District 
Court.  (18:16) 

5.  The  federal  government  be  requested  to  appoint  additional  County  Judges  at 
large  to  specialize  in  assessment  appeals.  (18:19) 

6.  No  costs  be  charged  on  any  appeal  before  the  proposed  Assessment  Appeal 
Board.  (18:20) 

7.  Statutory  direction  be  given  that  costs  as  between  a  solicitor  and  his  client 
are  to  be  awarded  to  the  appellant  and  against  the  municipality  in  all  appeals  before 
the  County  or  District  Court  unless  the  Court  considers  that  the  appeal  is  frivolous 
and  vexatious  or  that  the  appellant  previously  has  withheld  pertinent  evidence. 
(18:20) 

8.  Existing  high  school  district  and  county  equalization  appeal  procedures  be 
repealed  and  the  appeal  procedures  recommended  for  other  property  and  business 
tax  matters  be  made  applicable.  (18:22) 

9.  The  right  to  apply  for  tax  relief  on  the  grounds  of  sickness  or  extreme 
poverty  be  withdrawn.  (18:23) 

SCHOOL  FINANCE 

1.  So  long  as  school  grants  are  on  a  calendar  year  basis,  the  existing  practice 
of  calculating  them  on  the  previous  calendar  year's  pupil  load  be  replaced  by  a 


The  numbers  in  brackets  following  each  recommendation  refer  to  the  chapter  and  paragraph 
where  it  is  made. 

232 


Chapter   7:    School   Finance 

system  of  calculations  that  reflects  school  enrolment  in  the  period  beginning  the  first 
school  day  of  September  of  the  calendar  year  preceding  that  in  which  the  grants 
are  paid.   (20:41) 

2.  In  the  event  that  school  finances  are  based  on  a  fiscal  year  that  coincides 
with  that  of  the  Province,  the  final  school  grant  instalment  be  based  on  calculations 
of  pupil  load  that  reflect  enrolment  in  September  of  the  fiscal  year  in  which  the 
grants  are  paid.   ( 20 :  42 ) 

3.  Provincial  treatment  of  the  recognized  extraordinary  expenditure  of  school 
boards  be  amended  so  that  the  grant  contribution  to  capital  expenditure  is  applied 
at  the  time  the  expenditure  is  incurred.   ( 20 :  47 ) 

4.  In  each  municipality,  the  assessment  of  corporations  that  cannot  under 
The  Assessment  Act  direct  their  taxes  for  school  support  be  segregated  into  a 
distinct  allotment  taxable  by  public  and  separate  school  boards  in  exact  proportion 
to  the  relative  pupil  enrolment  of  the  boards.    (20:57) 

5.  The  elementary  school  mill  rate  levied  in  any  given  year  against  the  cor- 
poration assessment  allotment  be  the  lower  of  the  pubhc  or  separate  school  mill 
rate  applicable  where  the  property  is  situated.   (20:58) 

6.  The  grants  on  behalf  of  municipal  inspectors'  salaries,  evening  courses,  indus- 
trial arts  and  home  economics  instruction  to  non-resident  pupils,  library  books, 
text-books,  small  secondary  schools,  and  televised  instruction  be  abolished  in  their 
present  form  and  incorporated  into  the  basic  structure  of  the  Ontario  Foundation 
Tax  Plan.    (20:64) 

7.  The  existing  grant  for  English,  French  and  citizenship  courses  for  new 
Canadians  be  abolished  and  that  the  Province  relieve  school  boards  of  all  costs 
arising  from  such  courses.   ( 20 :  65 ) 

8.  The  grants  for  free  milk,  trustees'  council  fees,  and  entering  larger  units 
of  administration  be  terminated.   (20:66) 

9.  All  future  grants  made  by  the  Province  for  vocational  school  construction  be 
integrated  under  the  provisions  of  the  Ontario  Foundation  Tax  Plan.   ( 20 :  69 ) 

10.  The  requisitioning  powers  of  public  school  boards,  separate  school  boards 
and  boards  of  education  be  terminated,  and  that  these  boards  levy  their  own  taxes 
to  be  collected  through  bills  issued  for  the  purpose  by  municipalities  and  payable 
at  times  distinct  from  those  at  which  municipal  tax  bills  are  payable.   (20:79) 

PROVINCIAL  GRANTS  TO  MUNICIPALITIES 

1.  The  Department  of  Highways  prepare  a  scheme  for  classifying  all  roads  in 
accordance  with  the  user  and  local  access  benefits  that  flow  from  them,  and  assign 
each  Ontario  road  and  street  to  its  appropriate  class  within  five  years  of  the 
publication  of  this  Report.    (21:24) 


The  numbers  in  brackets  following  each  recommendation  refer  to  the  chapter  and  paragraph 
where  it  is  made. 

233 


Recommendations 

2.  Upon  the  completion  of  the  road  classification  scheme,  provincial  road 
grants  be  based  on  total  expenditure  for  each  class  of  road  within  a  municipality, 
the  percentage  of  provincial  aid  to  coincide  with  the  percentage  of  user  benefits 
assigned  to  each  class  of  road.    (21:24) 

3.  Municipalities  be  given  the  right  to  appeal  the  classification  of  any  road  first 
to  the  Department  of  Highways,  and  then  to  the  Ontario  Municipal  Board,  which 
shall  have  the  right  to  require  further  studies  by  the  Department  of  Highways,  and 
whose  decision  shall  be  final.  (21 :25) 

4.  Transitional  measures  accompany  the  introduction  of  the  new  road  grants 
to  help  municipalities  adjust  to  changes  in  provincial  payments,  such  measures  to 
be  gradually  phased  out  within  five  years  of  the  introduction  of  the  new  grant 
system.  (21:26) 

5.  While  the  present  county  road  equalization  scheme  remains  in  effect,  no 
county  be  penalized  for  fiscal  efforts  that  enable  it  to  exceed  the  level  of  defined 
needs.  (21:29) 

6.  Development  roads  be  designated  by  the  Minister  on  the  sole  criterion  of 
population  sparsity,  and  a  list  of  roads  so  designated  be  tabled  annually  in  the 
Legislature.  (21:33) 

7.  Roads  designated  as  development  roads  either  be  under  provincial  jurisdic- 
tion or,  where  population  growth  is  likely,  be  provincially  supported  in  such  a 
manner  that  development  status  is  phased  out  over  a  period  of  no  more  than  ten 
years,  at  the  end  of  which  the  road  becomes  an  integral  part  of  the  municipal 
system.  (21:34) 

8.  A  report  on  all  special  considerations  giving  rise  to  provincial  road  assis- 
tance to  municipalities  that  cannot  be  geared  to  formulas  be  tabled  in  the  Legis- 
lature, together  with  the  dollar  amounts  of  special  provincial  assistance  involved. 
(21:35) 

9.  Provincial  grants  in  support  of  child  welfare  services  be  raised  to  a  rate  of 
80  per  cent.  (21:54) 

10.  The  level  of  provincial  grants  for  the  maintenance  of  inmates  of  munici- 
pal and  approved  private  homes  for  the  aged,  and  toward  the  maintenance  of  elderly 
persons  in  satisfactory  alternative  accommodation  under  municipal  auspices,  be 
increased  to  80  per  cent.  (21 :57) 

1 1 .  The  Province  provide  all  persons  who  become  indigent  with  premium-free 
insurance  under  the  Ontario  Hospital  Care  Insurance  Plan,  without  a  waiting 
period.    (21:59) 

12.  The  level  of  provincial  grants  towards  homemakers'  and  nurses'  services 
be  increased  to  80  per  cent.  (21 :60) 


The  numbers  in  brackets  following  each  recommendation  refer  to  the  chapter  and  paragraph 
where  it  is  made. 

234 


Chapter  7:  Provincial  Grants  to  Municipalities 

13.  All  dollar  ceilings  on  existing  provincial  grants  to  conservation  authorities 
be  abolished.  (21:66) 

14.  Grants  on  behalf  of  weed,  warble  fly  and  plant  disease  control  be  abolished. 
(21:67) 

15.  All  health  grants  to  municipalities  for  such  specific  purposes  as  school 
nursing  inspection,  school  dental  services  and  venereal  disease  clinics  be  terminated. 
(21:68) 

16.  All  municipalities  providing  full-time  public  heahh  services  satisfactory  to 
the  Department  of  Health,  whether  individually  or  through  health  units,  be  eligible 
for  a  provincial  grant  of  50  per  cent  of  their  public  health  expenditures.    (21:72) 

17.  The  ceiling  on  the  Department  of  Social  and  Family  Services  grant  for  the 
construction  of  low-rental  housing  for  the  aged  be  removed.    (21:80) 

18.  Upon  the  creation  of  any  unit  of  regional  government,  the  Province  ter- 
minate all  existing  grants  for  recreation  and  community  services  to  the  municipalities 
within  the  region  in  favour  of  a  Community  Enrichment  Grant  payable  to  the 
regional  government.  (21:88) 

19.  All  recreation  and  community  service  grants  now  applicable  to  the  Munici- 
pality of  Metropolitan  Toronto  and  its  constituent  municipalities  be  terminated 
forthwith  in  favour  of  a  Community  Enrichment  Grant  of  $2  per  capita  payable  to 
the  Municipality  of  Metropolitan  Toronto  for  apportionment  between  Metro  and 
its  constituent  municipalities.    (21:89) 

20.  All  provincial  grants  on  behalf  of  the  administration  of  justice  be  abolished. 
(21:91) 

2 1 .  The  grants  payable  to  municipalities  under  provisions  of  The  Fire  Depart- 
ments Act  and  The  Pohce  Act  be  abolished.  (21 :92) 

22.  Provincial  grants  on  behalf  of  municipal  expenditure  for  wolf  and  fox 
bounties  be  abolished.  (21 :93) 

23.  The  Municipal  Unconditional  Grants  Act  be  repealed.  (21:94) 

24.  The  Province  pay  to  each  tax-levying  local  authority  a  Basic  Shelter 
Exemption  Grant  calculated  annually  by  applying  the  authority's  mill  rate  to  the 
aggregate  of  the  basic  shelter  exemptions  applicable  to  residential  and  farm  prop- 
erties within  its  boundaries.    (21 :96) 

25.  There  be  paid  annually  to  all  municipalities  now  receiving  assistance  under 
The  Municipal  Unconditional  Grants  Act  a  new  unconditional  grant  providing, 
for  the  relief  of  all  property  taxpayers,  an  initial  rate  of  $7.00  per  capita  for  the  first 
2,500  of  population,  an  increase  of  500  per  capita  for  the  next  2,500  of  population, 
and  an  additional  increase  of  500  for  each  subsequent  doubling  of  the  population. 
(21:98) 

26.  The  unconditional  grant  be  based  on  the  population  reported  annually  by 
the  municipality  for  assessment  purposes.    (21 :  100) 

235 


Recommendations 

27.  The  Province,  through  Cabinet  or  an  appropriate  organ  thereof,  make  a 
comprehensive  annual  review  of  provincial-local  finance  and  give  yearly  approval 
to  all  grant  programs .   ( 2 1 : 1 04 ) 

28.  In  instituting  a  comprehensive  annual  review  of  provincial-local  finance, 
the  Province  employ  an  expert  staff  to  conduct  continuing  studies  of  the  fiscal  and 
economic  condition  of  local  governments.   (21 :  105 ) 

29.  The  Province  publish  and  table  in  the  Legislature  a  report  on  its  annual 
review  of  provincial-local  finance,  giving  special  emphasis  to  the  fiscal  and  economic 
condition  of  local  governments.  (21 :  106) 

30.  The  Province,  upon  reviewing  the  five-year  capital  budgets  of  municipalities 
and  prevailing  economic  conditions  in  Ontario,  be  authorized  to  meet  all  of  the 
interest  and  other  costs  of  temporary  borrowing  required  to  advance  the  initiation 
of  municipal  capital  projects.    (21 :  107) 

MUNICIPAL  DEBT 

1 .  Payment  of  provincial  grants  be  scheduled  throughout  the  year  to  help  ensure 
an  orderly  flow  of  funds  to  meet  the  expenditure  patterns  of  the  recipient  local 
authorities.    (22:65) 

2.  The  present  limit  on  municipal  borrowing  for  current  purposes  be  replaced 
by  new  provisions 

(a)  setting  new  statutory  limits  based  solely  on  the  last  adopted  estimates  of 
revenue  for  a  full  year; 

(b)  permitting  borrowing  without  prior  approval  within  the  limits  of  15 
per  cent  of  such  revenues  without  notice,  and  of  25  per  cent  with  a  full 
explanation  given  to  the  Province  within  30  days  of  the  borrowing; 

(c)  permitting  borrowing  in  excess  of  25  per  cent  of  such  revenues  only  with 
prior  approval  of  the  Province,  and,  if  municipal  councillors  undertake 
such  borrowing  witliout  provincial  approval,  applying  the  present  penalty 
of  disqualification  from  holding  office  for  two  years;  and 

(d)  empowering  the  Province  to  require  municipalities  that  borrow  in  excess 
of  1 5  per  cent  of  revenues  to  create  and  maintain  a  working-fund  reserve 
through  a  contribution  of  up  to  3  per  cent  of  the  current  levy.  (22:68) 

3.  The  maximum  term  of  capital  borrowing  for  each  type  of  asset,  based  upon 
a  realistic  concept  of  its  anticipated  useful  life,  be  set  out  in  a  schedule  to  a  Regula- 
tion prescribed  by  The  Municipal  Act,  in  lieu  of  the  present  provisions  of  the  Act 
fixing,  or  empowering  the  Ontario  Municipal  Board  to  fix,  the  term  of  capital  debt. 
(22:91) 

4.  Municipal  corporations  and  each  of  their  associated  local  boards  be  required 
to  provide  in  their  annual  estimates  amounts  for  capital  purposes  equal  to  the 
lesser  of: 


The  numbers  in  brackets  following  each  recommendation  refer  to  the  chapter  and  paragraph 
where  it  is  made. 

236 


Chapter  7:  Municipal  Debt 

(a)  the  amount  of  capital  expenditures  in  their  five-year  capital  budget  that 
remains  to  be  financed,  and 

(b)  a  statutorily  specified  percentage  of  their  estimated  current  expenditures. 
(22:107) 

5.  A  municipality  or  local  board  be  permitted  to  make  provision  without  limit 
for  capital  expenditures  from  revenue,  provided  that  each  such  provision  is  clearly 
identified  in  the  annual  estimates  of  the  body  concerned  at  the  time  that  they  are 
adopted.   (22:109) 

6.  For  the  purposes  of  the  Annual  Report  of  Municipal  Statistics  and  prepara- 
tion by  council  and  assessment  of  municipal  capital  budget  submissions  prerequisite 
to  provincial  approval  of  borrowing,  the  capital  debt  of  a  municipality  be  deemed 

(a)  to  include  the  proportion  of  the  debt  for  which  it  or  its  ratepayers  are 
responsible  that  has  been  incurred  by  the  Ontario  Water  Resources  Com- 
mission, the  Central  Mortgage  and  Housing  Corporation,  a  public  or 
separate  school  board,  or  any  similar  local  authority,  commission  or 
corporation,  and 

(b)  to  exclude  school  debt  to  the  extent  that  the  debt  charges  on  such  debt 
are  being  met  by  provincial  grant.  (22:114) 

7.  The  provision  for  referendum  on  money  by-laws  be  abolished  and  instead: 

(a)  the  provincial  authority  responsible  for  approving  borrowings  be  required 
to  give  electors  or  persons  qualified  to  vote  on  money  by-laws  an  oppor- 
tunity to  speak  at  a  hearing  prior  to  making  a  decision  on  an  application; 

(b)  municipal  councils  be  required  to  give  owners  and  other  persons  qualified 
to  vote  on  money  by-laws  notice  of,  and  an  opportunity  to  speak  at,  any 
council  meeting  at  which  it  is  proposed  to  discuss  expenditures  that  will 
be  financed  through  borrowing  beyond  the  year.  (22: 126) 

8.  (a)    Every  municipality  be  required  each  year  to  submit  for  provincial 

approval  a  capital  budget  for  a  period  of  at  least  five  years; 

(b)  upon  approval  of  each  capital  budget  or  any  amendment  thereto,  a 
municipality  be  permitted  to  effect  without  further  approval  the  bor- 
rowing required  for  the  proposals  scheduled  therein  for  commence- 
ment in  the  first  year;  and 

(c)  upon  effecting  any  borrowing  so  permitted,  the  municipality  be 
required  to  notify  the  Province  forthwith.    (22: 128) 

9.  The  responsibility  for  giving  all  approvals  of  municipal  borrowings  required 
by  statute  be  transferred  from  the  Ontario  Municipal  Board  to  the  Department  of 
Municipal  Affairs.  (22:132) 

10.  The  effective  interest  rates  on  all  forms  of  provincial  lending  to  municipal- 
ities be  reviewed  regularly  and  maintained  at  a  uniform  level  at  a  small  margin 
above  the  ordinary  market  rate.   ( 22 : 1 35 ) 

237 


Recommendations 

11.  On  changing  the  system  of  grants  so  as  to  pay  school  boards  the  pro- 
vincial share  of  capital  costs  instead  of  debt  charges,  the  practice  of  lending  through 
the  Ontario  Education  Capital  Aid  Corporation  be  aboUshed.    (22: 138) 

12.  The  Province  periodically  review  federal  borrowing  arrangements  open  to 
Ontario  municipalities  with  the  object  of  either  obtaining  the  elimination  of  the 
borrowing  aspects  from  what  are  essentially  conditional  grant  programs  or  opting 
out  of  the  arrangements  altogether.    (12:141) 

13.  Municipal  corporations  be  required  to  carry  out  capital  borrowing  for 
separate  school  boards  in  the  same  manner  as  for  other  school  boards.  (22:144) 

14.  The  Department  of  Municipal  Affairs  give  study  to  ways  in  which  a  broader 
and  more  active  market  might  be  developed  for  municipal  debentures.    (22:148) 

RECONCILING  STRUCTURE  WITH  FINANCE 

1.  The  provincial  government  plan  and  schedule  the  detailed  studies  of 
boundaries,  functions  and  forms  of  municipal  organization  needed  to  establish  a 
comprehensive  system  of  regional  government  within  five  years  of  the  publication 
of  this  Report.  (23:151) 

2.  All  regional  governments  be  specifically  charged  with  the  functions  of 
assessment,  tax  collection  and  capital  borrowing  on  behalf  of  their  constituent 
municipalities.  (23:152) 

3.  For  as  long  as  it  proves  impracticable  to  include  a  municipality  or  other 
reasonably  settled  community  under  tlie  aegis  of  a  governmental  region,  the 
Province  undertake  to  make  available  appropriate  regional  services  on  a  contractual 
basis.  (23:153) 

4.  In  devising  a  scheme  of  regional  government  for  Ontario,  the  Province  take 
the  necessary  steps  to  integrate  secondary  education  as  a  regular  responsibility  of 
the  regional  council.  (23:165) 

INTRODUCTION  TO  VOLUME  III 

1 .  After  due  study,  the  form  of  the  Public  Accounts  be  revised  so  as  to  provide 
a  comprehensive  and  more  meaningful  presentation  of  the  revenues,  expenditures 
and  financial  position  of  the  provincial  government  and  all  its  agencies.  (24:13) 

2.  In  addition  to  the  financial  statements  prepared  by  the  Provincial  Auditor, 
government  revenues  and  expenditures  be  classified  and  presented  on  a  national 
accounts  basis.  (24:14) 

PROVINCIAL  REVENUE  LEGISLATION: 
ADMINISTRATION  AND  APPEALS 

1 .  The  Government  of  Ontario  establish  a  Department  of  Provincial  Revenue 
responsible  for  the  administration  of  all  revenue  statutes  now  administered  by  the 
Treasury  Department  under  the  Comptroller  of  Revenue.  (25:7) 


The  numbers  in  brackets  following  each  recommendation  refer  to  the  chapter  and  paragraph 
where  it  is  made. 

238 


Chapter  7:  Provincial  Revenue  Legislation 

2.  A  review  be  made  of  all  revenues  not  at  present  collected  by  the  Treasury 
Department  with  a  view  to  consolidating  revenue  administration  in  the  proposed 
Department  of  Provincial  Revenue.  (25:8) 

3.  Statutory  provision  be  made  for  the  regular  audit  of  agents  who  collect 
taxes,  and  that,  except  in  cases  of  misrepresentation,  fraud,  or  failure  to  remit  tax 
collected,  assessments  for  unpaid  tax,  together  with  interest,  be  limited  to  the  two- 
year  period  before  the  audit,  but  that  interest  continue  to  nm  thereafter  until  the 
taxes  assessed  are  paid.  (25: 11 ) 

4.  All  revenue  statutes  that  provide  for  collection  through  a  "billing"  or 
"self-assessing"  method  include  the  requirement  that  any  assessment  by  the  Prov- 
ince be  made  "with  all  due  dispatch"  and  that,  in  the  absence  of  misrepresentation 
or  fraud,  interest  imposed  for  the  period  prior  to  assessment  or  reassessment  for 
any  deficiency  in  tax  be  limited  so  that  it  does  not  extend  beyond  two  years  from 
the  date  that  the  return  was  filed,  or  required  to  be  filed,  whichever  is  later.  (25:12) 

5.  All  revenue  statutes  prohibit,  except  for  fraud  or  misrepresentation,  any 
reassessment  of  a  taxpayer  after  the  expiry  of  six  years  from  the  date  of  the  first 
or  original  assessment  or  after  any  shorter  period  of  time  specified  in  an  applicable 
intergovernmental  tax  collection  agreement.  (25:13) 

6.  Each  revenue  statute  require  that  administrative  officials,  boards  or  com- 
missions state  fully  and  clearly  in  writing  to  the  person  involved  the  authority  or 
basis  of  their  actions,  together  with  the  reasons  by  which  they  justify  their  actions, 
and  that,  where  the  privacy  of  the  person  is  not  affected,  these  reasons  be  published 
whenever  this  is  deemed  to  be  in  the  public  interest.  (25 : 1 4) 

7.  The  Government  of  Ontario  publish  from  time  to  time  Information 
Memoranda  setting  out  administrative  interpretation  and  procedures  of  its  revenue 
statutes.   (25:15) 

8.  Fees  for  the  issuance  of  collectors'  and  agents'  licences  be  abolished  and 
that  no  collector's  or  agent's  licence  be  refused  issuance  or  reissuance  except  upon 
failure  to  obtain  a  surety  bond  when  required.  (25:17) 

9.  Provision  be  made  in  all  revenue  statutes  for  a  right  of  refund  where 
overpayment  has  been  made,  whether  under  mistake  of  fact  or  of  law.  (25:20) 

10.  Appropriate  statutory  provision  be  made  for  interest  to  be  paid  in  respect 
of  aU  overpayments.  (25:21 ) 

1 1 .  The  penalty  provisions  in  all  revenue  statutes  provide  that  interest  is  to  be 
payable  in  respect  of  overdue  amounts  at  a  uniform  rate,  in  excess  of  the  maximum 
rates  ordinarily  charged  by  banks,  to  be  set  periodically  by  the  Lieutenant 
Governor  in  CouncU.  (25:23) 

12.  All  revenue  statutes  provide  a  reasonable  but  effective  penalty  for  delin- 
quent and  late  filing  of  returns,  and  grant  to  the  minister  responsible  discretionary 
power  to  allow,  where  appropriate,  extensions  of  time  for  the  filing  of  tax,  informa- 
tion and  other  returns.  (25:24) 

239 


Recommendations 

1 3.  All  revenue  statutes  that  provide  for  liens  against  the  property  of  delinquent 
taxpayers  give  authority  to  the  Minister  responsible  to  issue  certificates  of  no 
claim  for  lien,  which  shall  be  binding  on  the  Crown  in  respect  of  a  transaction  in 
which  the  applicant  is  involved  that  is  completed  within  a  stated  period.  (25:26) 

14.  A  statutory  Board  of  Review  be  constituted  within  the  Treasury  Department 
to  hear  objections  to  the  assessment  of  taxes,  the  levying  of  other  charges,  and  any 
other  administrative  acts  performed  under  authority  of  the  revenue  statutes. 
(25:30) 

15.  On  the  recommendation  of  the  Chairman  of  the  Board  of  Review,  the 
government  publish  from  time  to  time  those  decisions  of  the  Board  that  are  matters 
of  general  public  interest.  (25:32) 

16.  Each  revenue  statute  provide  a  right  of  appeal  to  the  High  Court  of  Justice 
for  Ontario  from  any  assessment,  levy,  administrative  act  or  review  upon  obtain- 
ing leave  of  the  Court,  and  from  any  decision  of  the  Board  of  Review  as  a  matter 
of  right.  (25:33) 

17.  The  Chief  Justice  of  the  High  Court  be  requested  to  designate  one  or  more 
of  the  members  of  his  Court  as  a  judge  or  judges  in  revenue  appeals.  (25:35) 

18.  No  costs  be  charged  on  any  hearing  before  the  proposed  Board  of  Review. 
(25:36) 

19.  Statutory  direction  be  given  to  the  Supreme  Court  of  Ontario  to  award 
costs  as  between  a  solicitor  and  his  client  to  the  appellant  and  against  the  Crown 
unless  the  Court  considers  that  the  appeal  is  frivolous  and  vexatious  or  that  the 
appellant  had  previously  withheld  pertinent  evidence.  (25 :37) 

20.  All  revenue  statutes  provide  that  security  for  costs,  if  any,  be  at  the  dis- 
cretion of  the  Court.  (25 :38) 

21.  Wherever  a  revenue  statute  imposes  a  time  limit  within  which  to  take  a 
step  in  the  appeal  procedure,  such  limit  be  extended  on  application  to  the  Supreme 
Court  of  Ontario  upon  such  terms  as  the  Court  thinks  equitable  under  the  circum- 
stances. (25:39) 

22.  A  Select  Committee  of  the  Legislature  on  Civil  Rights  in  Revenue  Legisla- 
tion be  appointed  to  make  a  periodic  review  of  all  revenue  statutes  of  Ontario  for 
the  purpose  of  ascertaining  whether  or  not  a  constant  and  uniform  policy  respecting 
the  rights  and  duties  of  citizens  is  being  maintained.  (25 :41 ) 

THE  PERSONAL  INCOME  TAX 

1.  Ontario  press  the  federal  government  to  consult  the  provinces  on  proposals 
for  changes  in  the  structure  of  the  personal  income  tax,  to  ensure  the  fullest  possible 
measure  of  agreement.  (26:126) 

2.  Ontario  press  the  federal  government  for  consultation  with  the  provinces  in 
respect  of  all  questions  relating  to  the  sufficiency  of  uniformity  between  the  federal 


The  numbers  in  brackets  following  each  recommendation  refer  to  the  chapter  and  paragraph 
where  it  is  made. 

240 


Chapter  7:  The  Personal  Income  Tax 

and  provincial  legislation,  and  to  the  adequacy  of  the  authority  provided  to  enable 
federal  collection  of  provincial  tax  and  administration  of  provincial  legislation. 
(26:128) 

3.  In  the  negotiation  of  any  future  fiscal  arrangements  with  the  federal  govern- 
ment, Ontario  press  for  a  provincial  sharing  in  the  yield  from  the  non-resident 
withholding  tax  computed  at  the  same  rate  as  the  rate  of  federal  abatement  for 
corporation  income  tax.  (26:130) 

4.  In  the  negotiation  of  any  future  fiscal  arrangements  with  the  federal  govern- 
ment, Ontario  press  for  provincial  sharing  in  the  yield  from  the  taxes  imposed  upon 
corporations  in  lieu  of  taxes  on  corporate  distributions  to  shareholders,  such 
provincial  sharing  to  be  in  the  same  proportion  as  the  personal  income  tax  abate- 
ment and  to  be  allocated  among  the  provinces  in  the  same  proportion  as  the 
income  of  each  corporation  liable  for  such  a  tax  is  allocated  for  purposes  of  the 
corporation  income  tax  abatement.  (26:133) 

5.  Ontario  press  for  amendments  in  the  provisions  of  the  tax  collection  agree- 
ment that  would  permit  it  to  notify  the  federal  government  of  its  intention  to 
change  its  rate  of  taxation  for  a  year  at  a  date  later  than  October  1  of  the  preceding 
year,  the  date  now  required.  (26:136) 

6.  Section  3(4)(a)  of  The  Income  Tax  Act  of  Ontario  be  amended 

(a)  to  provide  that  the  "tax  payable  under  the  Federal  Act"  for  purposes  of 
calculating  the  Ontario  income  tax  be  the  amount  as  defined  at  present 
plus  the  amount  of  any  credit  for  provincial  logging  tax  deducted  under 
Section  41 A  of  the  federal  Act,  and 

(b)  to  permit  an  individual  to  deduct  from  his  Ontario  income  tax  an  amount 
equal  to  one-third  of  the  tax  payable  by  him  under  The  Logging  Tax  Act. 
(26:162) 

7.  The  tax  credit  for  foreign  tax  under  The  Income  Tax  Act  of  Ontario  be 
determined  by  reference  to  income  "from  sources  in"  a  country  other  than  Canada, 
rather  than  income  "earned  in"  such  a  country.  (26:164) 

8.  The  amount  to  which  the  tax  credit  for  foreign  tax  is  limited  under  para- 
graph (b)  of  Section  3(6)  of  the  Act  be  a  proportion  of  the  tax  payable  under  the 
Act,  rather  than  a  proportion  of  the  abatement  for  provincial  tax  under  the  federal 
Act.  (26:165) 

9.  A  taxpayer  who  has  elected  to  average  his  income  under  the  federal  Income 
Tax  Act  be  similarly  treated  under  The  Income  Tax  Act  of  Ontario  even  if  he 
resided  in  another  province  or  earned  business  income  outside  Ontario  during  the 
averaging  period;  but  the  saving  in  Ontario  tax  resulting  from  the  election  to 
average,  be  limited  to  the  proportion  of  the  amount  otherwise  applicable  that  his 
income  attributable  to  Ontario  is  of  his  total  income  for  the  five-year  period. 
(26:168) 

10.  Provision  be  made  in  The  Income  Tax  Act  of  Ontario  requiring  that  a 
reassessment  be  made  if  the  amount  of  federal  tax  for  any  year  is  changed  by  a 

241 


Recommendations 

decision  of  the  Minister  following  the  filing  of  a  notice  of  objection,  or  by  a  decision 
of  the  Tax  Appeal  Board  or  a  Court.  (26: 170) 

THE  CORPORATIONS  TAX 

1 .  Ontario  seek  an  agreement  with  the  federal  government  for  the  collection  of 
corporate  income  taxes  under  which: 

(a)  a  copy  of  each  federal  corporate  tax  return  of  a  corporation  incorporated 
in  Ontario,  having  a  permanent  establishment  in  Ontario  or  carrying  on 
business  in  Ontario,  and  all  notices  of  assessment  thereof,  would  be  made 
available  to  the  Treasurer  of  Ontario,  either  by  the  federal  government 
or  by  the  taxpayer's  filing,  and 

(b)  the  federal  authorities  would  undertake 

(i)  upon  written  request  of  the  Treasurer  of  Ontario  to  conduct  an  audit 

of  an  Ontario  taxpayer's  return  and  advise  the  Treasurer  of  the  results, 

and 

(ii)  to  consult  regularly  with  the  Treasurer  of  Ontario  on  the  desirability 

of  any  proposed  changes  in  the  structure  of  the  tax  or  its  yield  to  the 

province.  (27:97) 

2.  In  the  event  that  Ontario  does  not  enter  into  a  corporate  tax  collection 
agreement  with  the  federal  government.  The  Corporations  Tax  Act  be  amended  to 
provide  that: 

(a)  every  corporation  shall  pay  a  tax  at  the  rate  specified,  computed  on  its 
taxable  income  earned  in  the  year  in  Ontario  as  determined  under  the 
provisions  of  the  Income  Tax  Act  (Canada)  and  the  Regulations  there- 
under, except  as  otherwise  specifically  provided  in  The  Corporations  Tax 
Act; 

(b)  all  discretions  exercised  by  the  Minister  of  National  Revenue  under  the 
Income  Tax  Act  (Canada)  shall  be  deemed  to  have  been  exercised  by  the 
Treasurer  of  Ontario  unless  the  Treasurer  exercises  a  discretion,  when  the 
determination  made  by  the  Treasurer  shall  prevail; 

(c)  all  elections  made  by  a  taxpayer  under  the  Income  Tax  Act  (Canada) 
shall  be  deemed  to  have  been  made  for  purposes  of  The  Corporations  Tax 
Act  unless  otherwise  specifically  provided  in  that  Act;  and 

(d)  every  corporation  required  to  file  a  return  under  The  Corporations  Act 

(Ontario)  shall  file  with  the  Treasurer  each  year  a  copy  of  its  return 
filed  under  the  Income  Tax  Act  (Canada),  and  a  copy  of  every  election, 
pension  plan  or  other  document  filed  with  the  Department  of  National 
Revenue  under  any  provision  of  the  Income  Tax  Act  (Canada).  (27: 111) 

3.  The  present  capital  and  place-of-business  taxes  under  The  Corporations 
Tax  Act  be  replaced  by  an  annual  corporate  business  tax  of  fixed  amount  payable, 
without  any  reduction  for  corporate  income  taxes,  by  every  corporation  now  liable 
for  the  present  taxes;  and  that  the  amount  of  the  tax  be  fixed  at  the  rate  or  rates 


The  numbers  in  brackets  following  each  recommendation  refer  to  the  chapter  and  paragraph 
where  it  is  made. 

242 


Chapter  7:  The  Corporations  Tax 

needed  initially  to  yield  approximately  the  same  revenue  as  derived  from  the  present 
taxes.   (27:125) 

4.  Upon  entering  into  any  agreement  with  the  federal  government  for  the 
federal  collection  6f  Ontario's  corporate  income  taxes,  the  proposed  annual 
corporate  business  tax  be  collected,  together  with  the  annual  filing  fee  under  The 
Corporations  Information  Act,  by  the  Department  of  the  Provincial  Secretary. 
(27:125) 

5.  The  special  taxes  under  The  Corporations  Tax  Act  applicable  to  banks,  rail- 
ways, telegraph  companies,  express  companies,  sleeping  car,  parlour  car  and  dining 
car  companies  be  repealed,  and  such  corporations  be  subject  to  the  recommended 
annual  corporate  business  tax.  (27:133) 

6.  The  provisions  of  the  Ontario  Corporations  Tax  Act  relating  to  searches 
and  seizures  be  amended  to  provide  safeguards  to  protect  the  rights  of  a  person 
whose  property  has  been  seized  by  giving  him  the  right 

(a)  to  apply  to  a  court  for  a  review  of  the  action  taken, 

(b)  to  inspect  and  list  the  seized  documents,  and 

(c)  to  obtain  the  return  of  seized  documents  upon  the  substitution,  where 
practical,  of  properly  identified,  clear  photo  copies  of  such  documents. 
(27:141) 

7.  Provisions  be  made  in  The  Corporations  Tax  Act  for  a  procedure  to  be 
followed  when  solicitor-client  privilege  is  claimed  in  respect  of  documents  that  are 
demanded  or  seized.  (27:  142) 

8.  The  Corporations  Tax  Act  provide  that  a  prosecution  for  an  offence  under 
the  Act  must  be  commenced  within  five  years  from  the  day  on  which  the  matter 
of  the  information  or  complaint  arose  or  within  one  year  from  the  day  on  which 
an  oflicer  of  the  Branch  first  had  sufficient  knowledge  to  justify  a  prosecution  for 
the  offence.  (27:144) 

THE  TAXATION  OF  WEALTH:   DEATH  AND  GIFT  TAXES 

1.  Except  where  a  deceased  was  domiciled  in  another  province  of  Canada  at 
death,  a  beneficiary  of  the  deceased  who  was  ordinarily  resident  in  Ontario  through- 
out the  twelve  months  preceding  his  death  be  made  subject  to  Ontario  succession 
duty  in  the  same  circumstances  that  he  would  be  subject  to  duty  if  the  deceased 
were  domiciled  in  Ontario  at  death.    (28:64) 

2.  The  Government  of  Ontario  make  representations  to  the  federal  government 
to  change  its  situs  rules  to  conform  with  those  in  force  in  the  provinces,  failing 
which  the  Government  of  Ontario  request  a  constitutional  amendment  allowing  the 
Province  to  adopt  situs  rules  identical  with  those  contained  from  time  to  time  in 
the  Estate  Tax  Act.   ( 28 :  69 ) 

3.  Tax  credits  be  allowed  from  Ontario  succession  duty  for  taxes  paid  to 
another  province  of  Canada  or  a  jurisdiction  outside  Canada  in  respect  of  property 

243 


Recommendations 

that  under  Ontario's  situs  rules  was  situated  therein,  and  for  75  %  of  federal  estate 
tax  in  respect  of  property  that  under  Ontario's  situs  rules  was  situated  in  a  province 
that  does  not  impose  succession  duty,    (28:70) 

4.  Ontario  take  appropriate  steps  to  eliminate  double  taxation  resulting  from 
differing  interpretations  of  the  common  law  situs  rules  that  are  made  in  other 
jurisdictions.    (28:71) 

5.  The  Succession  Duty  Act  be  amended  so  as  to  make  it  clear  that  any 
property  in  which  the  deceased  had  a  life  interest  but  which  he  did  not  own  is  not 
property  passing  on  death.   (28:72) 

6.  Upon  the  implementation  of  our  recommendation  for  the  imposition  of  a 
gift  tax,  Ontario  adopt  the  test  of  "beneficial  interest  accruing  by  survivorship" 
as  the  method  of  valuing  joint  property  regardless  of  source  of  contribution. 
(28:79) 

7.  Articles  of  ordinary  household  furnishings  which  pass  to  the  surviving 
spouse  or,  where  there  is  no  spouse,  to  a  qualified  dependant  with  whom  the 
deceased  was  living  at  the  time  of  his  death,  be  exempt  from  duty.    (28:80) 

8.  For  the  purposes  of  The  Succession  Duty  Act,  property  held  in  community 
that  was  contributed  by  the  deceased  be  deemed  to  be  property  passing  on  death, 
and  a  debt  created  by  a  marriage  contract  be  disallowed  as  a  deduction  in  deter- 
mining the  aggregate  value  of  an  estate.    (28:82) 

9.  Life  interests  be  valued  according  to  a  modern  standard  mortality  table, 
and  at  a  compound  interest  rate  that  more  closely  reflects  current  rates  of 
interest.    (28:84) 

10.  The  provisions  of  The  Succession  Duty  Act  permitting  the  life  tenant 
of  an  estate  to  pay  duties  on  an  instalment  basis  be  continued  but 

(a)  the  amount  of  each  instalment  of  duty  be  computed,  having  regard  to  his 
expectancy  of  life  according  to  the  standard  of  mortality  prescribed  for 
the  purpose  and  not  to  any  fixed  maximum  number  of  years,  and 

(b)  the  amount  be  payable  in  equal  annual  instalments  of  duty  and  compound 
interest  computed  at  the  same  rate  as  is  used  for  determining  the  value 
of  the  life  interest.   (28:88) 

1 1 .  Where  a  life  tenant  elects  to  pay  his  duties  on  an  instalment  basis,  the 
instalment  payments  be  payable  for  the  duration  of  his  Ufe  tenancy  whether  this  be 
longer  or  shorter  than  the  Ufe  expectancy  upon  which  the  instalments  were  com- 
puted. (28:89) 

12.  Where  the  life  tenant  has  chosen  to  pay  his  duties  by  instalments  and  the 
duties  payable  by  a  remainderman  have  been  computed  and  settled  as  at  the  date  of 
death  of  the  deceased,  the  remainderman's  duties  be  recomputed  when  he  falls  into 


The  numbers  in  brackets  following  each  recommendation  refer  to  the  chapter  and  paragraph 
where  it  is  made. 

244 


Chapter  7:  The  Taxation  of  Wealth:  Death  and  Gift  Taxes 

possession,  having  regard  to  the  actual  duration  of  the  life  tenancy,  and  a  refund 
be  made  or  additional  duties  collected  accordingly.    (28:90) 

13.  The  provisions  of  The  Succession  Duty  Act  permitting  the  life  tenant  of  an 
estate  to  pay  his  duties  within  six  months  of  the  death  of  the  deceased  be  con- 
tinued, but 

(a)  no  interest  be  allowed  for  paying  at  that  time  rather  than  by  instalments, 
and 

(b)  the  duties  of  the  life  tenant  and  those  of  any  remainderman  that  were 
settled  as  of  the  death  of  the  deceased  not  be  recomputed  upon  the 
termination  of  the  life  interest.   (28:91) 

14.  The  Succession  Duty  Act  provide  the  following  rules  for  the  computation 
and  payment  of  duties  where  one  or  more  beneficiaries  have  an  interest  in  expec- 
tancy in  the  income  of  an  estate  that  would  fall  into  possession  upon  the  decease 
of  a  preceding  life  tenant: 

(a)  If  the  primary  life  tenant  elects  to  pay  his  duties  by  instalments,  the 
duties  be  computed  on  the  basis  of  the  life  expectancy  of  himself  and  those 
beneficiaries  that  have  an  interest  in  expectancy  in  the  income  that  would 
be  enjoyed  after  the  death  of  a  predecessor  life  tenant;  and  such  instal- 
ments be  paid  by  him  for  his  lifetime  and  after  his  death  by  each  succeed- 
ing life  tenant  for  the  period  of  his  enjoyment; 

(b)  If  the  primary  life  tenant  chooses  not  to  pay  his  duties  by  instalments, 
the  duties  on  an  interest  in  expectancy  be  payable, 

(i)  within  six  months  of  the  death  of  the  deceased, 

(ii)  within  six  months  of  the  date  he  commenced  to  enjoy  his  interest 
in  expectancy,  or 

(iii)  by  equal  annual  monthly  instalments  of  principal  and  interest  pay- 
able for  his  lifetime  and  computed  according  to  his  life  expectancy 
at  the  date  he  commences  to  enjoy  his  interest  in  expectancy. 
as  the  beneficiary  may  elect; 

(c)  If  the  primary  life  tenant  elects  to  pay  his  duties  by  instahnents,  the 
remainderman's  duties  be  recomputed  when  he  falls  into  possession,  having 
regard  to  the  actual  duration  of  the  life  tenancies,  and  a  refund  be  made 
or  additional  duties  collected  accordingly;  and 

(d)  If  a  succeeding  life  tenant  elects  to  pay  his  duties  by  instalments,  the 
remainderman's  duties  be  recomputed  when  he  falls  into  possession, 
having  regard  to  a  duration  of  the  life  tenancies  deemed  to  be  the  life 
expectancy  of  the  primary  life  tenant  plus  the  number  of  years  that  the 
tenancy  was  enjoyed  by  the  succeeding  life  tenant.    (28:93) 

15.  An  annuity,  pension  or  similar  income  contract  be  valued  according  to  a 
modern  standard  mortality  table  and  at  a  compound  interest  rate  that  more 
closely  reflects  current  rates  of  interest.    (28:96) 

245 


Recommendations 

16.  The  provisions  of  The  Succession  Duty  Act  perniitting  the  beneficiary  of 
an  annuity,  pension  or  similar  income  contract  to  pay  duties  on  an  instalment 
basis  be  continued,  but  that 

(a)  the  computation  of  the  equal  annual  instalments  of  duty  include  com- 
pound interest  at  the  same  rate  per  annum  as  is  used  for  determining  the 
value  of  the  contract, 

(b)  the  amount  of  each  instalment  of  duty  in  respect  of  a  contract  providing 
payments  for  life  be  computed  having  regard  to  the  beneficiary's  expect- 
ancy of  life  and  not  to  any  fixed  maximum  number  of  years, 

(c)  the  amount  of  each  instalment  of  duty  in  respect  of  a  contract  providing 
payments  for  a  term  certain  be  computed  having  regard  to  that  term  and 
not  to  any  fixed  maximum  number  of  years,  and 

(d)  such  instalments  be  payable  for  each  year  during  which  payments  are 
received  under  the  contract  and,  where  the  contract  provides  payments 
for  life,  no  further  amounts  of  duty  be  payable  upon  termination  of  the 
contract  before  the  beneficiary  reaches  the  expectancy  of  life  upon  which 
the  duty  was  computed.    (28:97) 

17.  All  payments  made  voluntarily  on  or  after  the  death  of  a  deceased 
employee  in  recognition  of  services  rendered  by  him  be  dutiable,  with  provision 
for  payment  by  instalments  under  those  circumstances  where  instalments  would  be 
permitted  according  to  our  recommendation  28:  16  concerning  annuities.  (28:99) 

18.  Upon  the  implementation  of  our  recommendation  for  the  imposition  of  a 
gift  tax,  the  proceeds  from  policies  of  life  insurance  payable  as  a  result  of  the 
death  of  the  deceased  be  deemed  to  be  property  passing  on  death  only  to  the 
extent  that  the  policies  were  owned  by  the  deceased.  (28:102) 

19.  For  purposes  of  succession  duty,  statutory  recognition  be  given  to  the 
present  practice  of  making  allowance  for  partial  consideration  in  valuing  property 
passing  or  deemed  to  pass  on  the  death  of  the  deceased.    (28: 103) 

20.  The  Succession  Duty  Act  be  changed  to  exempt  absolute  dispositions 
made  more  than  three  years  before  the  death  of  the  deceased  rather  than  five  years, 
as  at  present.   (28:107) 

21.  The  affidavits  of  executors  and  beneficiaries  be  required  to  include  only 
those  absolute  dispositions  made  within  three  years  of  death  of  the  deceased  and 
dispositions  not  to  the  exclusion  of  the  donor,  whenever  made.   (28 :  108) 

22.  The  amount  of  any  gift  tax  payable  by  the  deceased  in  his  lifetime  be 
dutiable  to  the  extent  that  it  is  recoverable  as  a  deduction  from  federal  estate  tax 
or  provincial  succession  duties  or  by  way  of  refund  of  gift  tax.    (28:109) 

23.  A  disposition  be  valued  as  at  the  date  of  the  disposition.   (28 : 1 10) 

24.  The  Act  require  that  as  a  general  principle  all  dutiable  property  be  valued 
at  its  fair  market  value.   (28 : 1 1 1 ) 


The  numbers  in  brackets  following  each  recommendation  refer  to  the  chapter  and  paragraph 
where  it  is  made. 

246 


Chapter  7:  The  Tax.\tion  of  Wealth:  Death  and  Gift  Taxes 

25.  The  executor  or  administrator  of  an  estate  be  given  statutory  authority  to 
elect,  on  behalf  of  the  beneficiaries  collectively,  that  dutiable  property  and  transmis- 
sions be  valued  as  at  150  days  after  the  date  of  death,  except  that  assets  sold  before 
that  date  to  persons  with  whom  the  executor  was  dealing  at  arm's  length  be  valued 
at  the  amounts  realized  on  their  sale.   (28:115) 

26.  Appropriate  provision  be  made  for  adjusting  or  refunding  duties  when  a 
liability,  including  a  liability  that  was  contingent  at  the  death  of  the  deceased, 
becomes  payable  after  the  duties  have  been  settled,  provided  the  liability  or  liabili- 
ties so  payable  exceed  $1,000.    (28: 121 ) 

27.  All  expenses  in  connection  with  the  death  and  funeral  of  the  deceased  that 
are  paid  from  the  estate  be  treated  as  deductions  in  computing  aggregate  net  value. 
(28:122) 

28.  Amounts  paid,  not  exceeding  the  standard  tariff  of  the  applicable  county 
law  association,  for  legal  services  in  preparing  application  for  and  obtaining  pro- 
bate or  letters  of  administration,  preparing  succession  duty  and  estate  tax  returns, 
and  preparing  notarial  copies  of  letters  probate  or  letters  of  administration,  be 
allowed  as  deductions.  (28 :  123) 

29.  (a)   Dispositions  to  bona  fide  religious,  charitable  and  educational  organi- 

zations made  within  three  years  of  the  death  of  the  deceased  be 
included  in  the  aggregate  net  value  of  an  estate; 

(b)  bequests  to  bona  fide  religious,  charitable  and  educational  organiza- 
tions not  be  deductible  in  computing  the  aggregate  net  value  of  an 
estate;  and 

(c)  such  dispositions  and  bequests  be  exempt  from  duties  to  the  extent 
of  the  amounts  actually  paid  or  payable  to  such  organizations  outside 
Canada  as  may  be  prescribed  by  the  Lieutenant  Governor  in  Council 
and  to  all  such  organizations  in  Canada.    (28:127) 

30.  All  the  present  provisions  in  The  Succession  Duty  Act  for  giving  prefer- 
ential treatment  to  relatives  and  dependants  of  the  deceased  be  repealed.    (28: 133) 

31.  For  succession  duty  purposes,  the  widow  or  widower  of  the  deceased  be 
allowed  an  exemption  of  $75,000.    (28: 137) 

32.  For  succession  duty  purposes,  in  the  absence  of  an  exemption  to  a  spouse, 
the  same  exemption  as  for  a  spouse  be  given  to  a  person  who,  during  the  five  years 
prior  to  the  death  of  the  deceased,  resided  with  him,  was  dependent  upon  him  and 
managed  his  household  without  remuneration.    (28:138) 

33.  For  purposes  of  succession  duty,  a  child  of  the  deceased  under  twenty-one 
years  of  age  at  the  death  of  the  deceased  be  allowed  an  exemption  of  $25,000,  and 
that  an  older  child  of  the  deceased  be  allowed  an  exemption  of 

$22,000  if  21  years  of  age, 
19,000if  22yearsof  age, 
16,000if  23yearsof  age, 
13,000  if  24  years  of  age,  and 
10,000  if  25  years  of  age  or  more.   (28: 141 ) 

247 


Recommendations 

34.  For  purposes  of  succession  duty,  a  person  be  allowed  an  exemption  of 
$25,000,  if  he  was  at  the  death  of  the  deceased  wholly  dependent  upon  the 
deceased  for  support  by  reason  of  mental  or  physical  infirmity,  and  in  respect  of 
whom  the  deceased  was  entitled  to  a  dependant's  exemption  under  the  Income  Tax 
Act  (Canada)  for  the  taxation  year  ending  with  his  death  and  the  taxation  year 
preceding  that  year.   (28:142) 

35.  For  purposes  of  succession  duty,  a  child  of  the  deceased  who  has  no 
surviving  parent  and  who  had  been  wholly  dependent  upon  the  deceased  for  sup- 
port, and  in  resf>ect  of  whom  the  deceased  was  entitled  to  a  deduction  for  an 
exemption  under  the  Income  Tax  Act  (Canada)  for  the  taxation  year  ending  with 
his  death  and  the  taxation  year  preceding  that  year,  or  would  have  been  so  entitled 
if  the  dependant  had  then  been  born,  be  allowed  an  additional  exemption  equal  in 
amount  to  his  normal  exemption,  provided  that  if  the  aggregate  of  all  such  addi- 
tional exemptions  to  all  such  children  of  the  deceased  would  otherwise  exceed 
$75,000,  the  additional  exemption  for  each  such  child  be  reduced  proportionately 
so  that  the  additional  exemptions  aggregate  $75,000.   (28: 143) 

36.  For  purposes  of  succession  duty,  a  grandchild  whose  deceased  parent  was 
a  child  of  the  deceased  be  allowed  the  greater  of  any  other  exemption  to  which  he 
may  be  entitled  and  the  exemption  that  would  have  been  allowed  to  his  parent  had 
the  parent  been  living  and  sharing  in  the  estate  of  the  deceased,  provided  that  if 
there  are  more  than  one  such  grandchildren  the  exemption  that  would  have  been 
allowed  to  the  parent  be  divided  among  all  such  grandchildren.  (28:144) 

37.  For  purposes  of  succession  duty,  the  spouse  of  the  deceased  be  allowed  an 
additional  exemption  equal  to  the  aggregate  of  the  unused  portions  of  the  exemp- 
tions to  which  the  spouse's  dependent  children  were  entitled.    (28:145) 

38.  For  purposes  of  succession  duty,  the  aggregate  of  the  exemptions  allowed 
to  a  beneficiary  be  deductible  in  computing  the  net  taxable  value  of  the  benefits 
received  by  him  but  not  in  computing  the  aggregate  net  value  of  the  estate. 
(28:147) 

39.  For  purposes  of  succession  duty,  all  of  the  present  exemptions  in  respect 
of  small  amounts  of  property  passing  and  small  transmissions  and  dispositions  be 
abolished  and  there  be  enacted  an  exemption  for  dispositions  made  in  any  one 
year  to  any  one  person  that  do  not  exceed  $1,000.    (28: 148) 

40.  For  purposes  of  succession  duty, 

(a)  a  deduction  of  $6,000,  be  allowed  in  computing  the  aggregate  net  value 
of  each  estate,  being  an  amount  equal  to  the  aggregate  deduction  allow- 
able for  gift  tax  in  the  three  years  prior  to  the  death  of  the  deceased; 

(b)  a  deduction  be  allowed  in  computing  the  net  taxable  value  on  which  a 
beneficiary  is  liable  for  duties  of  that  portion  of  $6,000  that  is  reasonably 
apportionable  to  him;  and 


The  numbers  in  brackets  following  each  recommendation  refer  to  the  chapter  and  paragraph 
where  it  is  made. 

248 


Chapter  7:  The  Taxation  of  Wealth:  Death  and  Gift  Taxes 

(c)  each  beneficiary  be  given  a  tax  credit  equal  to  the  amount  of  gift  tax  paid 
or  payable  by  the  deceased  with  respect  to  gifts  made  to  him  by  the 
deceased  that  are  included  in  the  aggregate  value  of  the  estate  of  the 
deceased.   (28:151) 

41.  The  duties  payable  by  a  beneficiary  be  computed  as  follows: 

(a)  determine  a  basic  duty  by  applying  a  schedule  of  rates  to  the  aggregate 
net  value  of  the  estate; 

(b)  determine  the  beneficiary's  rate  computed  as  the  average  rate  of  basic 
duty  as  a  percentage  of  the  aggregate  net  value  of  the  estate,  or  50  per 
cent,  whichever  is  the  lesser; 

(c)  apply  the  beneficiary's  rate  to  the  net  taxable  value  of  the  property  passing 
to  the  beneficiary;  and 

(d)  in  the  event  that  the  federal  estate  tax  is  continued,  reduce  the  resultant 
amount  of  Ontario  duties  by  a  percentage  equivalent  to  the  unabated 
portion  of  the  federal  estate  tax.   (28 :  166) 

42.  A  schedule  of  rates  of  basic  duty  be  adopted  with  rates  that  are  pro- 
gressively higher  for  each  successive  additional  portion  of  aggregate  net  value 
ranging  from  15  per  cent  to  55  per  cent.   (28 :  166) 

43.  The  present  provisions  of  The  Succession  Duty  Act  relating  to  the  filing 
of  affidavits  be  amended 

(a)  to  require  a  beneficiary  to  include  in  his  affidavit  only  particulars  of  all 
dispositions  made  to  him  and  property  passing  to  him  or  to  his  benefit 
other  than  under  the  will  of  the  deceased  or  under  The  Devolution  of 
Estates  Act; 

(b)  to  designate  the  affidavit  of  the  executor  or  administrator  the  "Succession 
Duty  Return";  and 

(c)  to  require  the  affidavits  of  the  executor  or  administrator  and  the  bene- 
ficiaries to  be  filed  within  six  months  of  the  death  of  the  deceased. 
(28:170) 

44.  The  executor  or  administrator  of  an  estate  be  given  specific  statutory 
power  to  sell  all  or  part  of  the  property  included  in  any  bequest  to  a  beneficiary  if 
the  beneficiary  is  unable  or  unwilling  to  pay  the  duties  on  his  bequest.    (28:176) 

45.  The  right  of  the  beneficiary  of  an  interest  in  expectancy  to  defer  payment 
of  duties  until  he  falls  into  possession  be  continued.   (28: 178) 

46.  The  prohibition  against  opening  or  permitting  the  opening  of  a  safety 
deposit  box  or  other  repository  be  restricted  to  one  that  belongs  to  or  stands  in  the 
name  of  the  deceased  or  his  spouse,  either  alone  or  jointly  with  another  person, 
or  to  which  either  one  of  them  had  access;  and  a  person  who  permits  the  opening 
of  such  box  or  repository  without  knowledge  of  the  death  of  the  deceased  be  not 
liable  for  prosecution.   (28:183) 

249 


Recommendations 

47.  An  officer  of  each  branch  of  a  financial  institution  that  leases  safety  deposit 
boxes  be  appointed  an  agent  of  the  Treasurer  for  the  purpose  of  examining  and 
listing  the  contents  of  any  box  where  the  Treasurer's  consent  to  its  release  is 
required.  (28:184) 

48.  The  Treasurer  be  required  to  issue  within  a  specified  reasonable  time 
consents  to  transfer  assets  when  either  the  duties  have  been  paid  or  adequate 
security  for  payment  has  been  lodged.   (28 :  185 ) 

49.  Penalties  not  apply  to  persons  who,  with  reasonable  care,  have  dealt  with 
assets  of  the  deceased  under  circumstances  in  which  they  were  unaware  of  the 
death  or  of  the  beneficial  interest  of  the  deceased  in  such  assets.   (28 : 1 86) 

50.  The  statutory  authority  to  allow  postponement  of  duty  given  to  the  Lieu- 
tenant Governor  in  Council  under  Section  23  of  The  Succession  Duty  Act  be 
transferred  to  the  Treasurer  of  Ontario.    (28 :  196) 

51.  If  the  government  finds  that  special  succession  duty  treatment  is  desirable 
in  the  interests  of  woodland  conservation,  executors  and  administrators  of  estates 
be  given  the  right  to  elect  under  specified  conditions  to  pay  the  duty  on  timber, 
based  on  its  value  at  the  time  of  death,  as  it  is  cut  or  sold.    (28: 198) 

52.  The  statute  provide  that  the  Treasurer  be  required  to  issue  with  due  dis- 
patch a  notice  of  assessment  of  duty  to  each  person  who  benefits  from  an  estate 
or  from  dispositions  by  the  deceased,  whether  duty  is  payable  by  him  or  not,  and 
that  a  duplicate  of  each  such  notice  be  issued  to  the  executor  or  administrator  of 
the  estate.    (28:203) 

53.  A  beneficiary  subject  to  duties  on  Ontario  property  and  dispositions  from 
a  deceased  who  was  neither  domiciled  nor  resident  in  Ontario  be  assessed  duties 
on  the  aggregate  net  value  thereof  without  reduction  for  exemptions,  unless  all 
such  beneficiaries  and  the  executor  or  administrator  of  the  estate  elect  that  duties  be 
computed  in  the  ordinary  manner,  in  which  event  the  exemptions  for  each  bene- 
ficiary be  the  proportion  of  the  normal  exemptions  that  the  aggregate  net  value  of 
property  and  dispositions  dutiable  to  him  in  Ontario  is  of  the  aggregate  net  value 
of  all  property  and  dispositions  by  which  he  benefited.  (28:208) 

54.  All  dividends  having  an  Ontario  situs  declared  but  not  paid  prior  to  the 
death  of  a  deceased  who  was  neither  domiciled  nor  resident  in  Ontario  be  exempt 
from  succession  duties.   ( 28 :  209 ) 

55.  Ontario  introduce  a  gift  tax  applicable  to  individuals  and  personal  corpora- 
tions with  the  same  rate  structure  as  recommended  for  succession  duties,  and  that: 

(a)  a  gift  to  any  government  in  Canada  be  exempt; 

(b)  gifts  to  recognized  charitable,  educational  or  religious  organizations  be 
exempt; 

(c)  gifts  made  by  an  individual  in  the  year  to  any  one  person  not  exceeding 
$1,000  in  the  aggregate  be  exempt; 


The  numbers  in  brackets  following  each  recommendation  refer  to  the  chapter  and  paragraph 
where  it  is  made. 

250 


Chapter  7:  The  Taxation  of  Wealth:  Death  and  Gift  Taxes 

(d)  a  general  exemption  of  $2,000  be  allowed  each  year  to  an  individual  with 
respect  to  otherwise  taxable  gifts; 

(e)  gifts  used  directly  or  indirectly  to  pay  a  premium  on  any  contract  of 
insurance  on  the  life  of  the  donor  be  excepted  from  the  exemptions  in  (c) 
or  (d)  above;  and 

(f)  gifts  that  would  be  exempt  under  (d)  and  gifts  exceeding  $1,000  in  the 
year  to  any  one  organization  that  would  be  exempt  under  (b)  be  included 
in  the  aggregate  value  for  purposes  of  determining  the  rate  of  taxation, 
but  be  excluded  from  the  net  taxable  value  subject  to  the  tax.  (28:222) 

56.  Ontario  make  representations  to  the  Government  of  Canada  to  withdraw 
from  the  death  tax  field  on  the  understanding  that  Ontario  succession  duty  returns 
and  files  would  be  made  available  to  federal  officials  for  income  tax  purposes. 

(28:225) 

THE  RETAIL  SALES  TAX 

1.  All  food  products  for  human  consumption,  excluding  prepared  meals  and 
alcoholic  beverages,  be  exempt  from  retail  sales  tax.  (29:53) 

2.  Each  commercially  prepared  meal  sold  for  more  than  $1.50  be  taxed 
regardless  of  the  place  where  it  is  consumed.   (29:60) 

3.  The  present  exemptions  from  sales  tax  be  reviewed  and  revised  so  that: 

(a)  all  purchases  of  machinery,  equipment  and  other  goods  that  enter  into  the 
direct  costs  of  manufacturing  and  producing  will  be  exempt;  and 

(b)  purchases  of  all  goods  entering  into  indirect  costs  of  manufacturing  and 
producing  will  be  taxable.  (29:67) 

4.  The  present  provision  exempting  all  sales  of  less  than  210  be  amended  to 
exempt  sales  of  less  than  110.  (29:73) 

5.  The  present  exemption  from  sales  tax  for  draft  beer  sold  by  the  glass  on 
licensed  premises  be  repealed.  (29:74) 

6.  All  exemptions  of  tangible  personal  property  purchased  by  or  for  schools, 
school  boards,  universities,  hospitals,  nurses'  residences,  religious  institutions, 
Ontario  municipalities  and  publicly  supported  galleries  and  museums,  and  the 
exemption  for  buses  purchased  for  public  transportation  within  a  municipality  be 
repealed.  (29:78) 

7.  The  exemption  of  books,  magazines,  periodicals  and  religious  and  educa- 
tional publications  be  repealed.  (29:79) 

8.  The  exemption  of  students'  supplies  be  repealed.  (29:80) 

9.  The  Retail  Sales  Tax  Act  be  amended  so  as  to  impose  tax  on  an  appropriate 
list  of  services  other  than 

(a)  educational,  medical,  dental,  health,  funeral  and  transportation  services, 

(b)  services  the  dominant  use  of  which  is  made  by  business  firms, 

251 


Recommendations 

(c)  repair  and  maintenance  of  real  property,  and 

(d)  services  that  cannot  be  conveniently  taxed.  (29:93) 

10.  The  Ontario  retail  sales  tax  audit  staff  be  enlarged  sufficiently  to  ensure 
an  adequate  enforcement  program.  (29:105) 

1 1 .  Ontario  discontinue  the  payment  of  remuneration  to  vendors  for  the  collec- 
tion of  the  retail  sales  tax.  (29:108) 

12.  The  Province  be  made  a  preferred  creditor  rather  than  a  secured  creditor 
with  respect  to  sales  taxes  not  collected  by  a  bankrupt  vendor  but  for  which  he 
has  been  assessed.  (29:109) 

13.  The  provision  in  The  Retail  Sales  Tax  Act  giving  the  Comptroller  authority 
to  determine  the  fair  value  of  taxable  property  be  repealed.  (29:1 10) 

14.  The  definition  of  "use"  in  The  Retail  Sales  Tax  Act  be  changed  to  exclude 
storage  of  goods  that  are  held  for  resale.  (29:1 12) 

15.  The  deposit  or  bond  of  3  per  cent  of  the  total  contract  price  required  of 
non-resident  contractors  carrying  out  a  contract  in  Ontario  be  revised  to  relate 
more  closely  to  the  proportion  of  construction  contract  prices  ordinarily  represented 
by  sales  tax.  (29:113) 

16.  The  definition  of  non-resident  contractors  be  changed  to  exclude  corpora- 
tions that  are  incorporated  in  Ontario.  (29:1 14) 

17.  Rentals  and  tangible  personal  property  be  taxable  except  on  the  amounts 
provided  therein  for 

(a)  property  and  services  on  which  the  lessor  was  subject  to  tax,  and 

(b)  interest  and  other  financing  costs.  (29: 115) 

18.  The  present  exemption  for  gifts  be  enlarged  to  exempt  from  retail  sales 
tax  all  gifts  from  one  individual  to  another,  including  those  made  by  way  of 
transactions  for  inadequate  consideration.  (29:116) 

19.  The  Government  of  Ontario  negotiate  with  the  other  provincial  govern- 
ments to  establish  more  effective  means  of  collecting  sales  tax  on  goods  sold  in 
one  province  that  are  delivered  to  customers  in  another  province.  (29:120) 

20.  The  Government  of  Ontario,  together  with  the  other  provincial  govern- 
ments, negotiate  with  the  federal  government  to  obtain  its  agreement  to  collect  on 
behalf  of  the  provinces  provincial  sales  taxes  upon  the  importation  of  goods  into 
Canada.  (29:121) 

MOTOR  VEHICLE  REVENUES 

1.  The  remuneration  for  collecting  fuel  taxes  paid  to  "collectors"  under  The 
Gasoline  Tax  Act  and  to  "registrants"  under  The  Motor  Vehicle  Fuel  Tax  Act  be 
gradually  eliminated  over  the  next  five  years.  (30:15) 


The  numbers  in  brackets  following  each  recommendation  refer  to  the  chapter  and  paragraph 
where  it  is  made. 

252 


Chapter  7:  Motor  Vehicle  Revenues 

2.  The  retail  sales  tax  be  levied  on  gasoline  and  other  motive  fuel,  on  a  price 
base  that  includes  any  fuel  tax  that  is  applicable.  (30:21) 

3.  Any  fuel  tax  paid  on  motive  fuel  for  any  use  other  than  that  of  propelling 
a  vehicle  on  a  public  road  be  wholly  refundable,  and  any  sales  tax  thereon 

(a)  be  wholly  refundable  when  paid  by  farmers  or  commercial  fishermen,  and 

(b)  be  refundable  to  the  extent  based  on  the  refundable  amount  of  fuel  tax 
when  paid  by  others.  (30:27) 

4.  The  licensing  fees  for  all  commercial  vehicles  owned  by  municipalities, 
school  boards,  local  boards  and  commissions  be  set  at  the  same  levels  as  the  fees 
for  privately  owned  vehicles.  (30:41) 

5.  The  fee  for  licensing  trolley  buses  be  raised  from  the  present  flat  $2  to  at 
least  the  standard  rates  that  apply  to  motor  buses.  (30:44) 

6.  The  fees  charged  for  operating  licences  under  The  Public  Commercial 
Vehicles  Act  and  The  Public  Vehicles  Act  be  set  at  a  level  such  that  the  revenue 
derived  will  approximate  the  costs  incurred  in  administering  these  two  Acts. 
(30:53) 

7.  The  fees  for  the  various  categories  of  garage  licences  be  reduced  to  a  level 
such  that  the  revenue  derived  will  approximate  the  cost  of  licensing.  (30:58) 

8.  The  transfer  fee  charged  to  purchasers  of  motor  vehicles  be  reduced  to  a 
level  such  that  the  revenue  derived  will  approximate  the  cost  of  registering  the 
transfers.  (30:59) 

9.  Toll  charges  for  the  use  of  the  Burlington  and  the  Garden  City  Skyways  be 
eliminated.  (30:79) 

10.  The  licence  fee  for  passenger  vehicles,  dual-purpose  vehicles  and  trucks 
weighing  less  than  2Vi  tons  gross  weight  be  set  at  a  flat  rate  of  $25,  and  the  licence 
fee  for  trucks  from  IVz  to  3  tons  gross  weight  be  raised  to  $30.  (30:107) 

OTHER  PROVINCIAL  TAXES 

1.  The  Hospitals  Tax  Act  be  repealed  and  all  expenditures  on  amusements 
and  entertainment  be  taxable  under  the  retail  sales  tax.  (31:32) 

2.  The  tax,  on  a  person  holding  a  horse  racing  meeting,  of  $1  for  each  day  of 
racing,  be  abolished.  (31:47) 

3.  The  security  transfer  tax  be  abolished,  and  commissions  charged  by  security 
dealers  and  brokers  for  their  services  be  taxable  under  the  retail  sales  tax;  and  for 
this  purpose,  where  no  commission  is  charged  by  a  security  dealer  or  broker,  a 
reasonable  commission  be  deemed  to  have  been  charged.  (31:61) 

4.  The  land  transfer  tax  be  abolished  and  that  commissions  charged  for  services 
by  real  estate  agents  be  made  subject  to  the  retail  sales  tax.  (31:71) 

5.  The  tax  on  fire  insurance  premiums  imposed  under  The  Fire  Marshals  Act 
be  abolished.  (31:84) 

253 


Recommendations 
REVENUE  FROM  MINES 

1.  (a)    The  profits  tax  under  The  Mining  Tax  Act  be  revised  so  as  to  impose 

on  the  profits  of  a  mine  derived  from  both  mining  and  processing 
operations  a  two-stage  tax  consisting  of 
(i)   a  flat-rate  Mines  Services  Tax  from  which  payments  to  designated 

mining  municipaUties  and  other  public  service  expenditures  related 

to  mining  would  be  financed,  and 
(ii)  a  flat-rate  Mines  Profits  Tax  which  would  yield  an  appropriate 

return  for  the  use  of  Ontario's  mining  resources. 

(b)  The  profits  subject  to  the  Mines  Profits  Tax  be  the  profits  subject  to  the 
Mines  Services  Tax  less  the  Mines  Services  Tax  and  the  deductions 
hereinafter  recommended  by  us.  (32:61) 

2.  No  basic  exemption  be  allowed  with  respect  to  the  profits  subject  to  either 
the  proposed  Mines  Services  Tax  or  the  Mines  Profits  Tax.  (32:64) 

3.  Payments  to  gold  mines  under  the  Emergency  Gold  Mining  Assistance  Act 
be  excluded  from  the  computation  of  profits  subject  to  the  proposed  Mines  Profits 
Tax.  (32:71) 

4.  The  provision  permitting  the  Minister  of  Mines  to  remit  the  mining  tax  on 
iron  ore  smelted  in  Canada  be  repealed.  (32:73) 

5.  (a)    The  base  for  computing  the  investment  allowance,   deductible  from 

profits  subject  to  the  proposed  Mines  Profits  Tax, 
(i)   include  the  gross  investment  of  the  mine  operator  at  the  end  of  the 
taxation  year  in  all  assets  acquired  for  the  purpose  of  the  mining 
and  processing  operations,  as  well  as  the  unamortized  portion  of 
exploration  and  development  expenditures,  and 
(ii)  exclude  the  investment  in  mining  lands  or  any  interest  in  mining 
lands, 
(b)    For  the  purpose  of  computing  the  allowance,  the  investment  of  the 
mine  operator  in  unamortized  exploration  and  development  expenditures 
and  in  depreciable  property  be  the  cost  thereof  less  amounts  deducted, 
deductible  or  deemed  to  have  been  deducted  by  way  of  amortization  or 
depreciation  in  the  taxation  year  and  in  prior  taxation  years.  (32:81) 

6.  So  long  as  Ontario  continues  to  exempt  processing  profits  from  mining  tax, 

(a)  the  general  processing  allowance  be  determined  in  accordance  with  pro- 
visions in  The  Mining  Tax  Act  or  Regulations  thereunder,  and  that  the 
formula  be  revised  so  as  to  compute  the  allowance  on  the  written-down 
value  rather  than  the  original  cost  of  assets  used  for  processing,  without 
any  minimum  or  maximum  limitation  of  the  allowance  based  on  combined 
mining  and  processing  profits,  and 

(b)  the  special  processing  allowance  to  nickel  mines  be  abolished.  (32:90) 


The  numbers  in  brackets  following  each  recommendation  refer  to  the  chapter  and  paragraph 
where  it  is  made. 

254 


Chapter  7:  Revenue  From  Mines 

7.  The  profits  subject  to  the  proposed  Mines  Services  and  Mines  Profits  Taxes 
be  reduced  by  depreciation  allowances  on  depreciable  assets  employed  in  mining 
and  processing  at  the  rates  now  set  out  in  the  Act,  provided  that  where  it  can  be 
demonstrated  that  the  life  of  the  mine  is  less  than  6%  years,  the  Lieutenant 
Governor  in  Council  may,  upon  the  recommendation  of  the  Minister  of  Mines, 
allow  a  greater  rate  based  upon  the  expected  life  of  the  mine.  (32:95) 

8.  All  expenses  allowable  for  income  tax  purposes,  with  the  exception  of 
interest  and  financing  costs,  royalties  and  rentals  in  respect  of  mining  lands  or  rights 
other  than  those  payable  to  the  Crown,  municipal  property  taxes  and  allowances 
for  depletion  of  a  mine,  be  allowable  in  computing  profits  of  a  corporation  subject 
to  the  proposed  Mines  Services  and  Mines  Profits  Taxes,  in  whole  if  the  corpora- 
tion had  no  other  business  activity  or  source  of  income,  and  to  the  extent  reasonably 
apportionable  to  the  business  of  mining  and  processing  if  it  did  have  another 
business  activity  or  source  of  income.  (32:96) 

9.  The  profit  subject  to  the  proposed  Mines  Profits  Tax  be  reduced  by  the 
amount  of  taxes  paid  by  the  mine  operator  to  all  municipalities  and  school  boards 
on  non-exempt  property  used  directly  or  indirectly  for  the  purposes  of  deriving 
income  from  mining  or  processing.  (32:99) 

10.  (a)  The  profits  subject  to  the  proposed  Mines  Profits  Tax  be  mandatorily 

reduced  by  the  amount  of  expenditure  on  exploration  in  Ontario 
incurred  in  the  year,  and  incurred  in  previous  years  but  not  deductible  in 
such  years,  but  that  such  deduction  be  limited  to  the  amount  of  profits 
otherwise  subject  to  the  tax; 

(b)  the  profits  subject  to  both  the  proposed  Mines  Services  Tax  and  the 
proposed  Mines  Profits  Tax  be  reduced  by  an  annual  allowance  of  10 
per  cent  of  expenditures  on  mine  development  in  Ontario,  which,  at 
the  option  of  the  mine  operator,  may  be  increased  to  a  rate  not  exceed- 
ing 20  per  cent,  provided  that  where  it  can  be  demonstrated  that  the 
life  of  a  mine  is  less  than  five  years,  the  Lieutenant  Governor  in 
Council  may  upon  the  recommendation  of  the  Minister  of  Mines  allow 
a  greater  rate  based  upon  the  expected  life  of  the  mine;  and 

(c)  the  above  allowances  be  deductible  from  the  combined  profits  of  all 
mines  operated  by  the  taxpayer  in  Ontario,  but  that  the  allowance  for 
mine  development  expenditures  not  commence  until  the  year  that  the 
mine  for  which  the  expenditures  are  incurred  comes  into  production  in 
reasonable  commercial  quantities.  (32:114) 

1 1 .  For  the  purpose  of  computing  the  deductions  from  profits  for  exploration 
and  development,  and  the  investment  allowance,  a  mine  operator  who  has  incurred 
exploration  expenditures  and  expenditures  for  the  development  of  a  mine  that  had 
not  come  into  production  in  reasonable  commercial  quantities  at  the  effective  date 
of  the  revised  system  of  taxation  which  we  recommend,  or  that  had  come  into 

255 


Recommendations 

production  in  the  four-year  period  prior  to  the  effective  date,  be  deemed  to  have 
been  allowed  in  respect  of  such  expenditures  in  the  period  prior  to  the  effective 
date  of  the  new  system  the  greater  of 

(a)  the  amounts  actually  deducted  in  the  computation  of  his  mining  tax  under 
the  old  system,  or 

(b)  20  per  cent  for  the  year  that  the  mine  came  into  production  and  20  per 
cent  for  each  year  thereafter  prior  to  the  effective  date  of  the  new  system. 
(32:117) 

12.  The  profits  subject  to  the  proposed  Mines  Profits  Tax  be  reduced  by  losses 
from  mining  and  processing  incurred  in  the  five  preceding  and  the  two  succeeding 
taxation  years,  to  the  extent  that  profits  of  any  preceding  taxation  year  have  not 
already  been  reduced  by  such  losses,  but  that  such  deduction  be  fimited  to  losses, 
excluding  an  investment  allowance,  incurred  in  the  fiscal  year  that  the  proposed 
system  becomes  effective  and  in  subsequent  years.  (32:121) 

13.  The  proposed  Mines  Services  Tax  be  established  at  the  flat  rate  required 
to  yield  an  amount  approximately  equivalent  to  the  aggregate  of  the  payments  to 
be  made  by  the  Province  to  designated  mining  municipalities,  and  the  proposed 
Mines  Profits  Tax  be  established  initially  at  the  rate  of  12  per  cent.    (32:130) 

14.  The  administration  of  The  Mining  Tax  Act  be  transferred  from  the  Depart- 
ment of  Mines  to  be  proposed  Department  of  Revenue.    (32:135) 

15.  Pending  any  revision  of  the  structures  of  Ontario  mining  tax  and  federal 
income  tax,  Ontario  press  the  federal  government  for  a  change  in  Regulation  701 
under  the  Income  Tax  Act  so  that  mining  taxes,  except  to  the  extent  that  they  are 
imposed  on  processing  profits  or  other  income  which  is  not  derived  from  mining, 
will  be  fully  deductible  from  income  for  federal  income  tax  purposes.  (32:141) 

16.  Upon  the  adoption  of  the  revised  system  of  taxing  mining  profits  recom- 
mended by  us,  Ontario  press  the  federal  government  to  make  such  changes  in 
Regulation  701  under  the  Income  Tax  Act  that  all  of  the  mining  tax  payable  by 
Ontario  mines  will  be  deductible  for  income  tax  purposes.    (32:142) 

17.  The  rate  of  acreage  tax  on  mining  lands  be  set  and  maintained  at  such 
level  as  is  needed  to  perform  the  function  of  discouraging  the  holding  of  mining 
lands  without  the  performance  of  adequate  exploration,  development  or  mining 
work.    (32:152) 

18.  Rentals  on  leased  mining  lands  and  mining  rights  be  set  on  the  basis  and 
at  the  rates  recommended  by  the  Select  Committee  on  Mining  of  the  Ontario 
Legislature  or  at  such  higher  level  as  is  needed  to  perform  the  function  of  dis- 
couraging the  holding  of  mining  lands  and  rights  without  the  performance  of 
adequate  exploration,  development  or  mining  work.    (32: 156) 


The  numbers  in  brackets  following  each  recommendation  refer  to  the  chapter  and  paragraph 
where  it  is  made. 

256 


Chapter  7:  Revenue  From  Forest  Resources 
REVENUE  FROM  FOREST  RESOURCES 

1,  The  present  ground  rent  and  fire  protection  charges  on  Crown  lands  be 
abolished  and  replaced  by  tenure  charges  fixed  at  rates  per  foot  of  allowable  cut 
based  on  sound  principles  and  on  further  study  by  the  Department  of  Lands  and 
Forests.    (33:35) 

2.  The  Department  of  Lands  and  Forests  make  appropriate  adjustments  in 
the  rates  of  Crown  dues  so  that  combined  tenure  charges  and  Crown  dues  per  cubic 
foot  cut  by  a  licensee,  whose  actual  cut  is  equal  to  his  allowable  cut,  will  approxi- 
mate the  amount  of  such  combined  charges  under  present  rates.  (33:37) 

3.  With  respect  to  privately  owned  forest  land,  fire-protection  charges  be 
reviewed  and  set  on  a  cost-recovery  basis.    (33:39) 

4.  In  the  negotiation  of  general  federal-provincial  fiscal  agreements,  Ontario 
offer  to  repeal  The  Logging  Tax  Act  in  return  for  an  additional  share  of  income 
taxes  imposed  upon  taxpayers  engaged  in  logging  that  approximates  the  present 
net  return  to  Ontario  from  the  existing  logging  tax  arrangement,  and,  pending  such 
repeal,  The  Logging  Tax  Act  be  amended  by  the  enactment  of  loss-carry-over 
provisions  similar  to  those  included  in  the  federal  Income  Tax  Act  and  The  Cor- 
porations Tax  Act  of  Ontario.  (33:46) 

REVENUE  FROM  OTHER  NATURAL  RESOURCES 

1.  In  accordance  with  the  general  principles  that  we  have  developed  for  the 
taxation  of  mines,  the  tax  on  production  of  natural  gas  be  changed  to  a  uniform 
flat-rate  profits-based  tax,  equivalent  to  1 2  per  cent  of  the  economic  rent  accruing  to 
the  producer.    (34:6) 

2.  The  proposed  profits-based  tax  on  a  producer  of  natural  gas  be  reduced  by 
an  amount  equivalent  to  75  per  cent  of  the  rentals  or  royalties  payable  under  leases 
from  the  Province  of  the  lands  from  which  the  production  is  derived.  (34:9) 

3.  A  tax  be  introduced  on  the  profits  derived  from  oil  production  on  the  same 
basis,  at  the  same  rate  and  with  the  same  relief  to  operators  on  Crown  lands  as 
recommended  for  natural  gas  production.    (34: 1 1 ) 

4.  A  review  be  made  of  the  terms  and  rates  of  hunting  and  fishing  licences. 
(34:32) 

REVENUE  FROM  ALCOHOLIC  BEVERAGES 

1 .  The  Liquor  Control  Board  of  Ontario  be  instructed  to  bring  its  mark-up  on 
so-called  "low-priced"  Canadian  spirits  into  line  with  the  mark-ups  that  it  appUes 
to  other  Canadian  spirits.    (35:33) 

2.  The  Liquor  Control  Board  of  Ontario  apply  the  same  mark-up  to  the  cost 
of  an  imported  spirit,  wine  or  malt  beverage  as  is  used  for  the  corresponding  class 
of  domestic  product .  (35:34) 

257 


Recommendations 

3.  The  Liquor  Control  Board  of  Ontario  purchase  Ontario  wines  at  prices  no 
higher  than  those  dictated  by  market  forces.    (35:35) 

4.  The  licence  fees  at  present  levied  on  breweries  and  wineries  be  altered  so 
that  the  revenue  will  approximate  the  costs  of  licensing  and  inspection.    (35:37) 

5.  The  tax  on  winery  store  sales  be  adjusted  so  that  the  rate  of  provincial 
revenue  from  sales  of  domestic  wine  in  winery  and  Liquor  Control  Board  stores 
will  be  equated  to  the  extent  possible  without  the  wineries  being  deprived  of  a 
reasonable  rate  of  return  from  their  retailing  operations.    (35:38) 

6.  The  gallonage  tax  on  breweries  be  set  at  a  single  rate  per  gallon  for  all 
beer  produced  and  sold  in  Ontario.    (35 :4l ) 

7.  The  price  of  beer  to  home  consumers  and  licensed  premises  be  made 
uniform.   (35:44) 

8.  The  licence  charge  based  on  beer  consumption  be  set  at  a  single  rate 
applicable  to  all  types  of  licensed  premises.    (35:47) 

9.  After  thorough  study  by  the  Liquor  Licence  Board,  liquor  licence  fees  be 
set  on  a  basis  such  that  in  addition  to  covering  all  issuing  and  regulatory  costs, 
they  will  appropriate  to  the  Province  any  monopolistic  profits  that  the  licensing 
system  has  made  possible.    (35:48) 

10.  The  financial  basis  of  the  agreements  whereby  municipalities  receive  pay- 
ments from  the  Liquor  Licence  Board  be  adjusted  so  that  such  payments  will 
reflect  as  closely  as  possible  the  cost  to  the  municipalities  of  enforcing  The  Liquor 
Control  Act  and  The  Liquor  Licence  Act.  (35:49) 

1 1 .  The  transfer  fees  now  in  effect  for  liquor  licences  be  abolished  and  replaced 
by  a  flat  fee  to  yield  an  amount  not  exceeding  the  administrative  costs  to  the 
Liquor  Licence  Board  of  effecting  and  regulating  transfers.   (35 :52) 

12.  The  fee  structure  now  in  effect  for  special  occasion  permits  be  abolished 
and  replaced  by  a  flat  fee  that  will  yield  an  amount  not  exceeding  the  administrative 
costs  borne  by  the  Liquor  Licence  Board  in  issuing  the  permits.    (35:54) 

13.  There  be  instituted  specific  procedures  for  transferring  to  the  Treasury 
on  a  regular  basis  the  surplus  cash  held  by  the  Liquor  Control  Board  of  Ontario. 
(35:56) 

14.  In  accounting  for  its  assets,  the  Liquor  Control  Board  of  Ontario  adopt 
the  depreciation  methods  that  normally  apply  in  private  business.    (35:59) 

15.  The  Liquor  Control  Board  of  Ontario  be  directed  to  institute  a  program  of 
continuing  research  into  the  revenue  and  other  effects  of  changes  in  the  prices 
of  spirits,  wine  and  beer  .  (35:87) 


The  numbers  in  brackets  following  each  recommendation  refer  to  the  chapter  and  paragraph 
where  it  is  made. 

258 


Chapter  7:  Revenue  From  Alcoholic  Beverages 

16.  The  Government  of  Ontario,  through  the  Liquor  Control  Board  of  Ontario 
and  the  Alcoholism  and  Drug  Addiction  Research  Foundation,  seriously  study 
the  feasibility  of  establishing  a  price  structure  that  would  take  as  its  primary  basis 
the  alcoholic  content  of  different  types  of  alcoholic  beverages.    (35:90) 

17.  Representations  be  made  to  the  federal  government  for  closer  federal- 
provincial  co-ordination  of  revenue  policies  relating  to  alcohoUc  beverages.  (35:91) 

PROVINCIAL  GOVERNMENT  ENTERPRISES 

1 .  The  Power  Commission  Act  be  amended 

(a)  to  define  cost  of  power  so  as  to  be  consistent  with  generally  accepted 
accounting  practices,  and 

(b)  to  require  billing  at  cost  plus  a  profit  margin  not  exceeding,  except  with 
the  approval  of  the  Lieutenant  Governor  in  Council,  a  specified  percentage 
of  the  cost.   (36:17) 

2.  Government-owned  business  enterprises  be  subject  to  income  taxes  under 
the  Ontario  Corporations  Tax  Act.    (36:21 ) 

3.  The  Province  consider  discontinuing  its  practice  of  guaranteeing  the  securi- 
ties issued  by  those  public  enterprises  whose  offerings  can  be  sold  readily  in  the 
open  market  on  acceptable  terms.    (36:23) 

OTHER  NON-TAX  REVENUES 

1 .  The  Financial  Administration  Act  be  amended  to  require  that  there  be  tabled 
in  the  Legislature  a  quinquennial  review  explaining  the  nature  and  level  of  all  fees 
charged  by  the  government.   (37:9) 

FINANCING  HOSPITAL  AND  MEDICAL  CARE 

1.  Ontario  negotiate  the  withdrawal  of  the  federal  government  hospital  con- 
struction grant  program  for  Ontario  hospitals  in  return  for  further  tax  room  or 
abatement  sufficient  for  Ontario  to  assume  the  responsibility  on  an  adequate  basis. 
(38:29) 

2.  Ontario  hospital  construction  grants  be  changed  from  a  per-bed  basis  to  a 
percentage  of  approved  construction  cost  basis.    (38 :30) 

3.  Ontario  hospital  construction  grants  be  broadened  to  cover  the  costs  of 
constructing  the  portions  of  the  hospital  which  are  to  be  used  for  administration 
and  servicing.   (38:31) 

4.  The  Ontario  Hospital  Services  Commission  allow  hospitals  to  include 
in  reimbursable  operating  costs  an  annual  amount  sufficient  to  amortize  over  a 
reasonable  period  the  cost  of  renovations,  alterations  or  other  major  repairs  that 
are  not  recovered  through  major  renovation  grants  and  that  would  result  in  com- 
mensurate operational  savings.    (38:32) 

259 


Recommendations 

5.  Upon  implementation  of  the  two  preceding  recommendations,  Ontario  dis- 
continue construction  grants  for  special  rehabilitation  facilities  and  tuberculosis 
sanatoria.    (38:33) 

6.  Ontario  negotiate  the  withdrawal  of  the  federal  government  hospital  operat- 
ing grant  program  for  Ontario  hospitals  in  return  for  tax  room  or  abatement 
sufficient  for  Ontario  to  assume  the  responsibility  on  an  adequate  basis.   (38:42) 

7.  Ontario  negotiate  the  withdrawal  of  the  federal  health  grants  program  in 
Ontario  in  return  for  tax  room  or  abatement  sufficient  for  Ontario  to  assume  the 
responsibility  on  an  adequate  basis.    (38:48) 

8.  Premium  rates  for  the  Hospital  Care  Insurance  Plan  be  maintained  at  a 
level  to  yield  roughly  one-third  of  the  total  financial  resources  required  to  meet 
operating  costs.    (38:71) 

9.  Consideration  be  given  to  replacing  the  present  two-tier  premium  structure 
of  the  Hospital  Care  Insurance  Plan  with  a  three-tier  structure  comparable  to 
that  of  the  Ontario  Medical  Services  Insurance  Plan.   (38:72) 

10.  When  future  changes  in  premium  levels  become  necessary,  consideration 
be  given  to  incorporating  into  the  Hospital  Care  Insurance  Plan  a  scheme  of 
subsidized  premiums  comparable  to  that  in  the  Ontario  Medical  Services  Insurance 
Plan.    (38:74) 

PROVINCIAL  DEBT  POLICY  TO   1975 

1.  As  a  partial  solution  to  its  projected  annual  expenditure-revenue  gaps,  the 
Province  permit  a  modest  expansion  of  its  net  debt  at  a  rate  at  least  equal  to  the 
growth  in  provincial  domestic  product.   (40:8) 

2.  In  any  given  period,  provincial  policies  concerning  appropriate  levels 
and  composition  of  taxation  and  expenditures  be  consciously  directed  towards  the 
objective  of  moderating  cyclical  fluctuations  within  the  Ontario  economy.    (40: 1 1 ) 


The  numbers  in  brackets  following  each  recommendation  refer  to  the  chapter  and  paragraph 
where  it  is  made. 


260 


Chapter 
8 


Fiscal  Effects  of 

the  Recommendations: 

Prescription  for  Future  Needs 


INTRODUCTION 

1.  The  three  hundred  and  fifty  or  so  recommendations  listed  in  the  preced- 
ing chapter  can  be  broken  down  into  four  categories.  First,  there  are  recom- 
mendations whose  impact  on  provincial  and  local  finance  is  direct  and  measurable. 
In  this  category,  for  example,  are  the  recommendations  that  would  subject  services 
to  sales  taxation,  remove  the  property  tax  exemption  of  institutions  of  higher 
learning,  provide  a  new  unconditional  grant  to  municipaUties,  or  introduce  a 
revised  provincial  mining  tax.  Second,  there  are  a  number  of  recommendations 
whose  impact  on  provincial  and  local  finance  is  direct,  but  defies  measurement  at 
this  time.  Thus,  for  instance,  the  province-wide  reassessment  we  recommend  will 
directly  affect  property  tax  yields  and  the  relative  burden  of  the  tax  on  different 
classes  of  taxpayers,  but  its  outcome  cannot  be  quantified  because  of  the  widely 
diverging  assessment  practices  that  now  prevail  in  Ontario  municipaUties.  Third, 
there  are  recommendations  that  affect  neither  the  base  nor  the  rates  of  taxes  and 
grants,  but  that  are  bound  to  have  indirect  effects  on  provincial  and  local  finance. 
Included  in  this  category  are  such  important  recommendations  as  those  that  seek 
the  creation  of  regional  governments  and  those  that  look  to  a  more  effective  and 


261 


Fiscal  Effects  of  the  Recommendations 

equitable  tax  appeals  system.  Fourth,  there  are  a  number  of  recommendations 
that  seek  to  enhance  the  equity  and  efficiency  of  the  revenue  system  through  purely 
structural  and  administrative  means.  A  uniform  fiscal  year  for  provincial  and  local 
governments,  and  improved  financial  reporting  by  all  governmental  authorities  are 
examples. 

2.  This  chapter  deals  only  with  recommendations  in  the  first  category,  that  is, 
those  whose  impact  on  provincial  and  local  finance  is  direct  and  measurable.  Its 
task  is  to  lay  before  the  reader  the  financial  impact  of  the  direct  and  quantifiable 
recommendations  made  in  Volumes  II  and  III,  and,  on  the  basis  of  their  con- 
sequences, to  outline  certain  other  measures  affecting  in  particular  the  level  of 
school  grants  and  of  provincial  tax  rates.  Taken  together,  these  measures  provide 
the  means  necessary  to  meet  provincial  and  local  requirements,  both  now  and  for 
the  foreseeable  future,  which  under  our  projections  is  the  year  1974-75.  They  are 
based  on  two  most  important  assumptions:  that  there  will  be  no  new  expenditure 
commitments  other  than  those  arising  from  the  re-allocation  of  provincial-local 
spending  responsibiUties  we  suggest,  and  no  changes  in  federal-provincial  fiscal 
arrangements.  Of  themselves  they  do  not  constitute  in  the  words  of  our  terms  of 
reference,  a  "tax  and  revenue  system  [that]  is  as  simple,  clear,  equitable,  efficient, 
adequate  and  as  conducive  to  the  sound  growth  of  the  Province  as  can  be  devised". 
The  development  of  this  system,  as  we  see  it,  hinges  as  well  upon  our  many  recom- 
mendations whose  fiscal  effects  are  either  immeasurable  or  indirect,  and  on  future 
patterns  of  federal-provincial  negotiation.  What  we  consider  in  this  chapter, 
therefore,  is  only  the  mix  of  tax,  grant  and  debt  policies  that,  in  our  judgment,  can 
best  meet  provincial  and  local  fiscal  requirements  under  prevailing  federal-provincial 
arrangements  in  the  light  of  the  quantitative  data  available  to  us. 

3.  The  material  that  follows  is  organized  in  three  parts.  In  the  first,  we  develop 
our  best  estimates  of  what  the  financial  picture  would  have  been  in  1966-67  had 
the  changes  we  contemplate  been  in  effect.  Because  this  exercise  can  be  based  in 
large  part  on  actual  data,  it  enjoys  the  greatest  degree  of  accuracy  possible  at  this 
time.  The  second  part  of  the  chapter,  which  is  subject  to  a  considerably  wider 
margin  of  error  than  the  first,  attempts  to  outline  the  fiscal  consequences  of  our 
recommendations  from  the  first  fiscal  year  in  which  they  could  take  effect — that  is 
to  say,  1968-69 — to  the  last  year  for  which  we  have  made  projections,  1974-75. 
In  the  third  and  final  part,  we  offer  a  commentary  on  our  over-all  sketch  of  the 
Ontario  fiscal  scene  with  particular  reference  to  the  broad  context  of  federal- 
provincial  fiscal  arrangements  and  to  adjustments  in  these  arrangements  which,  if 
successfully  negotiated,  might  modify  the  impact  of  the  revenue  measures  we  have 
had  to  contemplate. 

THE  FISCAL  SCENE  IN  1966-67 

4.  Table  8:1  launches  our  attempt  to  reconstruct  the  fiscal  year  1966-67  in  the 
light  of  our  quantifiable  recommendations.  This  Table  shows  our  estimates  of  the 
fiscal  impact  of  the  measurable  recommendations  that  affect  local  government.  All 
recommendations  whose  fiscal  effect  is  shown  in  the  Table  are  developed  in  Volume 

262 


Chapter  8:  Paragraphs  2-6 

II,  save  for  our  recommendation  extending  the  sales  tax  to  all  tangible  personal 
property  purchased  by  local  authorities,  made  in  Volume  III. 

Table  8:1 

THE  FISCAL    EFFECT  ON  LOCAL  GOVERNMENTS, 

HAD  RECOMMENDATIONS  MADE  IN  VOLUMES  II  AND  III 

BEEN  EFFECTIVE  IN  1966 

(millions  of  dollars) 

Actual  Tax  Levies  (Estimated)  960 

Deduct: 

Reduced  expenditure  from  provincial  assumption  of  the 

administration  of  justice  15 

Increased  revenue  from  new  unconditional  grant  to 
municipalities    32 

All  other  changes  in  grants  to  municipalities  (net)  15 

62 

Less  sales  tax  payable  by  local  governments  15  47 

Revised  Revenue  Requirement    913 

Deduct: 

Increase  in  provincial  payments  in  lieu  of  tax  on 
previously  exempt  property  38 

Basic  shelter  exemption  grant  Ill  149 

Revised  Levy  on  Local  Property  Taxpayers  764 


Local  Debt  Outstanding  at  End  of  Fiscal  Year  1,997 

Deduct: 

Reduction  in  borrowing  because  of  revised  school 
capital  grants  35 

Revised  Local  Debt  (Including  separate  school  debt  of 
$162  million)  1,962 

5.  The  first  figure  in  the  Table,  $960  million,  is  our  calculation  of  the  amount 
of  tax  actually  levied  on  property  in  1966.  From  this  amount  we  subtract  $62 
million,  which  represents  the  reduction  in  claims  on  the  property  tax  occasioned  by 
our  recommendations  that  the  Province  assume  complete  jurisdiction  over  the 
administration  of  justice  at  an  estimated  cost  of  $15  million,  pay  a  new  uncon- 
ditional grant  yielding  approximately  $32  million  more  than  the  one  in  force  in 
1966-67,  and  rationalize  existing  conditional  grants  to  municipalities  with  a  net 
increase  in  aid  of  about  $15  million.  The  $62  million  reduction  is  then  offset  by 
an  increase  of  $15  million  in  local  government  outlays  occasioned  by  the  removal 
of  their  sales  tax  exemption  on  purchases  of  tangible  personal  property  to  yield  a 
revised  local  revenue  requirement  of  $913  million.  It  is  on  the  basis  of  this  $913 
million  requirement  that  local  govenmients  would  have  struck  their  mill  rates  had 
the  quantifiable  recommendations  made  in  Volumes  II  and  III  been  in  effect  in 
1966-67. 

6.  Under  our  recommendations,   $913   million  would  of  course  not  be  the 

263 


Fiscal  Effects  of  the  Recommendations 

amount  effectively  levied  on  local  property  taxpayers.  This  is  because  the  $913 
million  would  be  applicable  to  governmental  and  institutional  properties  hence- 
forth liable  for  full  provincial  payments  in  lieu  of  tax,  and  also  because  the 
Province,  through  the  basic  shelter  exemption  grant,  would  pay  either  the  tax 
levied  on  the  first  $2,000  of  the  provincially  equalized  taxable  assessment  of  each 
self-contained  residential  property,  or  50  per  cent  of  the  tax,  whichever  is  less. 
To  take  account  of  these  measures,  Table  8:1  deducts  from  the  $913  million  a 
total  of  $149  million,  which  is  the  sum  of  our  estimates  for  the  additional  payments 
in  lieu  of  tax  by  the  Province  ($38  million)  and  the  provincial  basic  shelter 
exemption  grant  ($111  million).  The  residue,  $764  million,  represents  the  effective 
1966  levy  under  our  recommendations  on  all  classes  of  local  property  taxpayers. 
The  reduction  in  the  burden  on  these  taxpayers  is  accordingly  in  the  order  of 
20  per  cent. 

7.  The  concluding  figures  in  Table  8:1  cover  the  effects  of  the  recommenda- 
tions on  the  debt  position  of  local  governments.  The  $1,997  million  appearing  in 
the  Table  is  our  estimate  of  the  actual  debt  carried  by  these  governments  at  the 
close  of  the  1966  fiscal  year.  It  can  reasonably  be  assumed  that  none  of  the 
changes  giving  rise  to  the  revised  effective  levy  on  property  taxpayers  would  have 
altered  the  debt  position  of  these  governments.^  At  this  point,  however,  we  can 
introduce  the  financial  effect  on  local  government  of  a  final  quantifiable  recom- 
mendation not  yet  taken  into  account.  We  refer  to  a  revised  grant  policy  toward 
school  capital  expenditures  whereby  the  Province,  from  the  year  of  implementation, 
would  make  once-and-for-all  grants  on  capital  costs  at  the  time  they  are  incurred. 
This  recommendation  would  not  affect  grant  recognition  of  debt  charges  on  behalf 
of  borrowing  undertaken  prior  to  the  year  of  implementation,  but  would  sub- 
stantially reduce  local  borrowing  from  that  year  on.  The  $35  million  shown  in 
the  Table  represents  our  estimate  of  this  reduced  local  borrowing  for  1966,  and 
leaves  a  revised  figure  for  outstanding  local  debt  under  our  recommendations  of 
$1,962  million,  including  separate  school  debt  of  $162  million. 

8.  Turning  now  to  Table  8:2,  the  scene  shifts  from  the  local  to  the  provincial 
level  of  government. 2  To  our  calculation  of  actual  provincial  expenditure  in 
1966-67,  $1,929  million,  are  added  all  the  items  of  increased  provincial  aid, 
including  school  capital  grants,  shown  in  Table  8:1.  Amounting  to  $246  million, 
these  items  yield  a  revised  provincial  expenditure  total  of  $2,175  million.  On  the 
reveruie  side,  actual  revenue  estimated  at  $1,789  miUion  is  increased  by  $132  mil- 
lion, being  the  sum  of  $128  million  additional  revenue  from  the  revised  sales  tax 
base  and  a  net  of  $4  million  from  all  other  tax  changes,  to  produce  revised 

^The  only  recommendation  in  this  category  that  could  potentially  affect  local  govern- 
ment debt  is  the  one  relating  to  the  provincial  assumption  of  all  responsibility  for  the 
administration  of  justice.  There  would  be  an  effect  on  debt  inasmuch  as  local  govern- 
ments had  financed  in  1966  the  construction  of  new  court  houses  and  jails  through 
debentures.  Under  our  recommendation,  such  construction  would  no  longer  entail 
local  outlays,  but  we  are  unable  to  estimate  the  consequent  amount  of  debt  reduction, 
if  any,  for  1966. 

'This  shift  involves  a  time  discrepancy  in  that  the  provincial  fiscal  year  begins  and  ends 
three  months  after  that  of  local  governments.  We  have  chosen  to  ignore  this  dis- 
crepancy, since  its  effect  on  the  magnitudes  under  discussion  is  marginal. 

264 


Chapter  8:  Paragraphs  7-9 

Table  8:2 

THE   FISCAL   EFFECT  ON  THE   PROVINCIAL   GOVERNMENT, 

HAD  RECOMMENDATIONS  MADE  IN  VOLUMES  II   AND  III 

BEEN  EFFECTIVE  IN   1966-67.* 

(millions  of  dollars) 

Expenditure 

Actual  Expenditure  (Estimated)t    1,929 

Add  proposed  increases: 

Administration  of  justice  15 

New  municipal  unconditional  grant  32 

Other  municipal  grants  (net)  15 

Payments  in  lieu  of  taxes  38 

Basic  shelter  exemption  grant  Ill 

New  school  capital  grants  35  246 

Revised  Expenditure   2,175 

Revenue 

Actual  Revenue  (Estimated)  1,789 

Add: 

Additional  revenue  from  new  sales  tax  base  128 

All  other  revenue  changes  (net)  4  132 

Revised  Revenue   1,921 

Deficit 

Actual  Deficit  (Estimated)  140 

Net  effect  of  changes  set  out  above  114 

Revised    Deficit  254 

Net  Capital  Debt  Actual  Revised 

Net  Capital  Debt  April  1,  1966  1,514  1,514 
Add: 

Deficit  for  year  ended  March  31,  1967  140  254 

Net  Capital  Debt  March  31,  1967   1,654  1,768 

♦Expenditures,   revenue   deficit   and   debt    reflect   advances   to   the    universities   through    the 
Ontario  Universities  Capital  Aid  Corporation  and  payments  for  debt  service  by  the  universities 
to  O.U.C.A.C. 
tDerived  from  Budget  Statement  of  the  Treasurer  of  Ontario,  1967. 

provincial  revenues  of  $1,921  million.  The  net  effect  of  all  revenue  and  expenditure 
changes  adds  $114  million  to  the  $140  million  deficit  actually  sustained  in  1966-67 
for  a  revised  provincial  deficit  of  $254  miUion.  Net  provincial  capital  debt  as  of 
the  end  of  the  fiscal  year  is  $1,768  million  in  contrast  lo  the  actual  figure  of 
$1,654  million. 

9.  So  much  for  the  fiscal  effect  on  provincial  and  local  governments  of  the 
quantifiable  recommendations  made  in  Volumes  II  and  III.  In  a  nutshell,  they 
have  made  possible  a  reduction  of  20  per  cent  in  the  effective  levy  on  local  property 
taxpayers  at  a  cost  to  the  Province  of  $246  miUion,  of  which  $132  miUion  is 
covered  by  recommended  provincial  tax  changes  and  $114  million  becomes  an 
addition  to  the  1966-67  provincial  deficit.    They  entail  no  change  in  the  existing 

265 


Fiscal  Effects  of  the  Recommendations 

level  of  provincial  grant  support  for  school  boards,  which  is  in  the  order  of 
45  per  cent  of  expenditures.  They  do  reflect  the  revised  grant  treatment  of  school 
capital  outlays  recommended  in  Volume  II,  but  the  effect  of  this  recommendation 
is  introduced  at  the  prevailing  level  of  provincial  school  support  only. 

10.  At  a  number  of  points  in  this  Report,  we  have  made  it  plain  that,  in  our 
opinion,  the  existing  level  of  provincial  grants  results  in  a  degree  of  school  board 
reliance  on  the  property  tax  that  is  unwarranted  because  of  the  patent  deficiencies 
of  this  tax.  Accordingly,  we  must  now  contemplate  a  revision  in  the  level  of 
provincial  grants  sufficient  to  substantially  reduce  local  recourse  to  the  property 
tax  for  school  purposes.  One  by-product  of  this  change  will  be  to  bring  the 
property  tax  into  somewhat  closer  conformity  with  the  benefit  principle.  But  in 
revising  the  level  of  provincial  grants,  we  are  of  the  opinion  that  three  supplemental 
considerations  are  of  importance.  The  first  is  that  school  board  autonomy  demands 
a  degree  of  reliance  on  local  taxes  sufficient  to  maintain  close  accountability  to  the 
public.  The  second  is  that  any  reduction  in  recourse  to  the  property  tax  must  be 
gauged  in  the  light  of  its  repercussion  on  the  level  of  other  taxes  and  on  the  result- 
ing distribution  of  government  benefits  and  costs  among  different  classes  of 
taxpayers.  The  third  is  the  fact  that  our  basic  shelter  exemption  grant  will  mitigate 
the  most  regressive  aspects  of  the  property  tax.  Ultimately,  of  course,  the  equity  of 
a  tax  system  depends  on  the  effective  distribution  of  expenditure  benefits  and  tax 
burdens  among  individuals. 

1 1 .  In  light  of  the  above,  we  point  out  that  the  quantifiable  recommendations 
made  elsewhere  in  this  Report  have  already  achieved  a  substantial  reduction  in  the 
property  tax  burden.  This  makes  it  possible  to  contemplate  a  level  of  school  grants 
that  is  consistent  with  the  objective  of  maintaining  school  board  responsibility 
through  a  realistic  degree  of  reliance  on  the  one  autonomous  revenue  source 
available  to  them:  the  property  tax.  Finally,  there  is  the  question  of  the  repercus- 
sion of  the  changes  on  rates  of  income  and  consumption  taxes  and  on  levels  of 
debt.  All  of  these  concerns  are  given  quantified  expression  in  Table  8:3,  where  we 
introduce  the  fiscal  effect  on  the  provincial  government  of  school  grants  designed  to 
finance,  on  the  average,  60  per  cent  of  local  education  costs. 

12.  Table  8:3  must  necessarily  repeat  a  good  deal  of  the  material  covered  in 
Table  8:2.  To  simplify  the  reader's  task  in  following  the  data,  we  accordingly  set 
out  in  italic  type  the  figures  in  Table  8:3  that  depart  from  those  in  Table  8:2. 

13.  Beginning  with  the  provincial  expenditure  picture,  the  first  major  change  is 
the  insertion  of  the  additional  cost  to  the  Province  of  school  grants  designed  to 
yield  60  per  cent  of  local  education  expenditure,  calculated  by  us  as  $136  million. 
Because  this  additional  aid  reduces  local  revenue  requirements,  it  is  offset  somewhat 
bv  reductions  in  the  two  recommended  provincial  contributions  shown  in  Table 
8:2  whose  level  depends  on  the  size  of  these  requirements.  We  refer  to  payments 
in  lieu  of  taxes,  which  now  become  $34  million  instead  of  $38  million,  and  to  the 
basic  shelter  exemption  grant,  which  falls  from  $111  million  to  $95  million. 
Finally,  the  new  school  capital  grants  rise  from  $35  million  to  $50  million  because 

266 


Chapter  8:  Paragraphs  10-13 


Table  8:3 

THE  FISCAL  EFFECT  ON  THE  PROVINCIAL  GOVERNMENT  FOR   1966-67, 

ASSUMING  CHANGES  RECOMMENDED  IN  VOLUMES  II  AND  III,  INCREASED 

PROVINCIAL  SCHOOL  GRANTS,  AND  TAX  RATE  CHANGES  NECESSARY  TO 

MAINTAIN  A  REASONABLE  RATIO  OF  DEBT  TO  PROVINCIAL 

DOMESTIC  PRODUCT 

(millions  of  dollars) 

Expenditure 

Actual  Expenditure  (Estimated)  1,929 

Add: 

Increased  grants  to  school  boards  136 

Administration  of  justice  15 

New  municipal  unconditional  grant  32 

Other  municipal  grants  (net)  15 

Payments  in  lieu  of  taxes  34 

Basic  shelter  exemption  grant  95 

New  school  capital  grants  50                        377 

Revised  Actual  Expenditure   2,306 

Revenue 

Actual  Revenue  (Estimated)  1,789 

Add: 

Additional  revenue  from  new  sales  tax  base  128 

All  other  revenue  changes  (net)  4  132 

Revised  Revenue   1,921 

Deficit 

Actual  Deficit  (Estimated)  140 

Net  effect  of  changes  set  out  above  - 245 

Revised  Deficit  before  tax  rate  increases  385 

Deduct  Additional  Revenue  from  tax  rate 

increases  of:   

8%   federal  basic  personal  income  tax  128 

1%  sales  tax  103 

1^     gasoline  tax  (1.4^  other  motor  fuels)  18  249 

Deficit  after  tax  rate  increases  136 

Net  Capital  Debt 

Net  Capital  Debt  April  1,  1966  1,514 

Add: 

Deficit  after  tax  rate  increases  136 

Revised  Net  Capital  Debt  March  31,  1967  1,650 

Increase  in  debt  allowed  for  new  school  capital 

grants  permitting  corresponding  reduction  in 

municipal  debt  50 

Remaining  Revised  Net  Capital  Debt  1,600 

Estimated  Provincial  Domestic  Product,  1966  20,500 

Remaining  Revised  Net  Capital  Debt  as  a  Percentage  of 
P-D.P 7.8% 


267 


Fiscal  Effects  of  the  Recommendations 

they  are  subject  to  the  over-all  increase  in  school  grant  levels  to  60  per  cent. 
With  the  other  items  of  provincial  expenditure  unchanged  from  Table  8:2,  Table 
8:3  shows  a  total  increase  in  spending  of  $377  million,  bringing  revised  actual 
expenditure  for  1966-67  to  $2,306  million.  Since  revised  revenues,  at  $1,921 
million,  are  unchanged  from  Table  8:2,  there  is  a  resulting  over- all  deficit  of 
$385  miUion,  of  which  $245  million  represents  the  net  increase  over  the  deficit  of 
$140  million  actually  sustained  in  1966-67. 

14.  It  is  abundantly  clear  that,  under  the  provincial  debt  policy  we  espouse 
and  shall  explain  shortly,  a  deficit  of  this  magnitude  could  not  have  been  tolerated. 
For  this  reason  we  are  forced  to  contemplate  tax  increases  in  three  revenue  fields: 
the  personal  income  tax,  the  sales  tax  and  the  gasoline  tax.  As  shown  in  Table 
8:3,  we  would  have  drawn  from  the  first  an  additional  $128  million  in  revenue, 
from  the  second  $103  million  and  from  the  third  $18  million.  Totalling  $249  mil- 
lion, these  revenue  increases  would  have  reduced  the  deficit  from  $385  million 
to  $136  milUon,  a  level  very  closely  comparable  to  the  $140  million  deficit 
actually  sustained,  according  to  our  calculations,  by  the  Province  in  1966-67. 

15.  It  now  behooves  us  to  explain  briefly  the  reasoning  behind  the  tax  increases 
we  contemplate.  These  admittedly  large  increases  are  the  direct  result  of  additions 
to  provincial  expenditure  designed  solely  to  reduce  local  government  recourse  to 
another  revenue  source,  the  property  tax.  To  hghten  property  tax  burdens  is  to 
cut  back  the  tax  that  our  incidence  study  shows  to  be  by  far  the  most  regressive. 
To  the  extent  that  property  tax  reductions  are  met  by  increases  in  the  personal 
income  tax,  they  are  financed  by  the  tax  that  is  best  in  accord  with  the  principle 
of  ability  to  pay.  Our  over-all  objective,  however,  is  an  Ontario  fiscal  system  that 
is  not  sharply  progressive  but,  as  explained  at  the  outset  of  this  volume,  moderately 
so.  For  this  reason,  we  are  hardly  prepared  to  finance  all  property  tax  reductions 
through  the  personal  income  tax.  To  follow  this  course  would  in  any  event  all  but 
preclude  such  future  personal  income  tax  increases  as  might  become  necessary,  to 
say  nothing  of  bringing  about  undesirably  sharp  rate  changes  in  but  a  single  year. 
Under  these  circumstances,  the  personal  income  tax  increase  of  8  per  cent  of  the 
federal  basic  tax  shown  in  the  Table,  all  of  which  would  have  been,  in  1966-67, 
a  net  addition  to  the  24  per  cent  provincial  tax  abated  by  the  federal  government, 
represents  what  to  us  is  the  maximum  advisable  reliance  on  this  tax  for  that  year. 
We  note  in  this  context  that  two  provinces  whose  personal  income  tax  is  collected 
by  the  federal  government  now  exceed  the  federal  abatement  by  5  percentage 
points. 

16.  Turning  now  to  consumption  taxes,  it  is  with  some  reluctance  that  we 
arrive  at  an  extra  1  per  cent  on  the  retail  sales  tax,  thereby  bringing  its  effective 
rate  from  5  to  6  per  cent.  Under  the  recommendations  in  Volume  III  whereby  we 
broaden  the  base  of  this  tax,  $128  million  has  already  been  added  to  its  weight. 
In  superimposing  the  $103  million  produced  by  our  1  percentage  point  rate 
increase,  we  are  in  effect  relying  upon  the  sales  tax  for  $23 1  million  in  additional 
revenue.    We  hasten  to  point  out,  however,  that  our  reluctance  is  due  far  more 

268 


Chapter  8:  Paragraphs  14-20 

to  the  sudden  introduction  of  a  change  of  this  magnitude  than  to  any  consequences 
in  equity.  Depending  on  the  family-income  group,  our  incidence  studies  show  that 
the  Ontario  retail  sales  tax  is  generally  proportional  or  mildly  progressive.  Because 
our  sales  tax  increase,  large  though  it  may  appear,  entails  corresponding  reductions 
in  the  regressive  property  tax,  the  equity  of  the  Ontario  fiscal  system  is  thereby 
enhanced.  The  same  comment  applies  to  the  equity  effect  of  our  illustrative 
increase  in  gasoline  and  diesel  fuel  taxes. 

17.  But  in  that  we  regard  motor  vehicle  fuel  taxes  as  closely  tied  to  road 
benefits,  there  are  limits  on  the  increases  that  can  be  contemplated  in  any  given 
year.  In  our  chapter  on  the  subject,  we  have  expressed  the  opinion  that  taxes  on 
road  users  should  yield  annually  no  less  than  65  per  cent  and  no  more  than  75 
per  cent  of  total  road  expenditures.  The  10  increase  we  show  for  1966-67  leaves 
the  yield  of  these  taxes  well  within  this  range. 

18.  For  the  purpose  of  our  1966-67  exercise,  we  do  not  choose  to  have 
recourse  to  rate  increases  in  any  other  tax  fields,  and  this  for  three  reasons.  First, 
taxes  on  property,  income  and  consumption  are  the  largest  revenue  producers  in 
Ontario.  Reduced  reliance  on  any  one  of  these  inevitably  entails  heavy  recourse  to 
the  others.  Second,  because  income  and  consumption  taxes  are  so  much  more 
equitable  than  the  property  tax,  equity  is  enhanced  by  financing  reduced  property 
tax  burdens  through  higher  income  and  consumption  taxes.  Third,  there  are  grave 
drawbacks  to  contemplating  early  increases  in  any  of  the  other  taxes.  Thus,  for 
example,  this  Report  advocates  far-reaching  structural  changes  in  succession  duties 
and  the  mining  profits  tax.  To  superimpose  rate  increases  on  a  newly  revised  tax 
structure  would  complicate  matters.  As  for  the  corporation  income  tax,  its 
uncertain  incidence  and  capricious  economic  effects  mark  it  as  a  decidedly  inferior 
source  of  additional  revenue.  None  of  this  is  to  say  that  we  would  refrain  from 
contemplating  increases  in  these  or  any  other  taxes  under  certain  circumstances. 
Such  increases  might  be  necessary  to  avoid  a  clearly  unacceptable  degree  of 
additional  reliance  on  income  and  consumption  taxes.  Fortunately,  however,  the 
1966-67  fiscal  picture  requires  no  such  drastic  measures. 

19.  With  $381  million  of  additional  revenue  in  hand,  and  a  resulting  deficit 
therefore  comparable  to  that  sustained  in  1966-67,  we  can  now  return  to  Table 
8:3.  Added  to  the  provincial  net  capital  debt  of  $1,514  million  at  the  beginning  of 
the  fiscal  year,  our  projected  deficit  of  $136  million  after  tax  rate  increases  yields 
an  end-of-year  debt  of  $1,650  million.  Is  this  an  acceptable  level  of  debt  for  the 
Province  of  Ontario? 

20.  In  the  chapters  of  Volume  I  and  III  that  we  devote  to  debt  policy,  we 
conclude  that  for  the  Province  of  Ontario  to  maintain  debt  at  a  relatively  constant 
ratio  of  provincial  domestic  product  would  constitute  a  basically  conservative 
fiscal  approach.  We  have  none  the  less  followed  this  approach  in  dealing  with 
the  period  covered  by  our  projection,  that  is  to  the  year  1974-75.  This  is  because 
our  projection  cannot  take  account  of  new  expenditure  programs  that  might  be 

269 


Fiscal  Effects  of  the  Recommendations 

generated  in  the  context  of  future  economic  growth.  Accordingly,  we  have  formu- 
lated the  rule  that  the  Province  should  maintain  debt  at  a  ratio  of  approximately 
9  per  cent  of  P.D.P.  In  any  given  year,  considerations  of  counter-cycUcal  fiscal 
policy  should  impel  the  Province  to  carry  forward  debt  increases  that  would  raise 
this  ratio  in  recession  and  reduce  it  in  prosperity.  As  economic  circumstances  in 
1966-67  were  unusually  buoyant,  the  pohcy  we  recommend  calls  for  an  end-of-year 
debt  somewhat  below  the  9  per  cent  ratio. 

21.  The  debt  level  projections  under  which  we  develop  our  9  per  cent  rule 
must  now  be  adjusted  to  take  account  of  our  recommendation  concerning  school 
capital  grants.  Under  the  grant  system  we  depict  for  1966-67,  the  Province  would 
have  contributed  60  per  cent  of  the  school  capital  outlays  made  in  that  year.  In 
addition,  however,  the  Province  would  have  reimbursed  local  governments  for  60 
per  cent  of  the  debt  charges  they  incurred  from  borrowing  in  earlier  years  under 
the  capital  grant  system  then  in  force.  It  follows  that  a  special  debt  allowance  is 
necessary  for  the  transitional  period  during  which  the  Province  simultaneously 
assumes  what  would  otherwise  become  local  school  debt  and  makes  grants  toward 
previously  incurred  local  debt  charges.  We  accordingly  introduce  in  Table  8:3  a 
calculated  allowance  of  $50  million,  thereby  producing  a  revised  net  capital  debt 
figure  of  $1,600  million.  Taken  as  a  proportion  of  P.D.P. ,  this  figure  yields  a 
debt-to-P.D.P.  ratio  that  we  deem  acceptable  in  a  year  of  unusual  economic 
buoyancy — 7.8  per  cent. 

22.  While  achieving  this  satisfactory  debt  level  in  a  setting  of  substantially 
enhanced  aid  to  local  government  has  necessitated  substantial  tax  increases,  we 
feel  bound  to  point  out  that  1966-67  is  a  most  favourable  year  in  which  to  attempt 
a  statistical  demonstration  of  the  effects  of  our  recommendations.  This  is  not 
simply  because  economic  prosperity  boosted  tax  yields  beyond  what  would 
normally  be  expected.  More  especially,  it  is  because  the  state  of  the  provincial 
accounts  on  which  we  base  our  exercise  is  considerably  more  unfavourable  than 
can  reasonably  be  expected  in  any  future  year.  In  Chapter  6  we  develop  a  set  of 
projections  that  show  an  ever-widening  gap  between  provincial  revenues  and 
expenditures  to  the  year  1974-75.  So  long  as  this  gap  remains  manageable,  as  it  is 
for  1966-67,  it  is  possible  to  implement  our  recommendations  through  provincial 
tax  increases  which,  though  large,  are  hardly  punitive.  But  subsequently,  as  the 
projected  gap  widens,  substantial  tax  increases  appear  unavoidable  simply  to  meet 
existing  provincial  commitments,  let  alone  finance  the  additional  ones  entailed  by 
our  Report.  Thus,  when  the  quantitative  impact  of  this  Report  is  assessed  for 
succeeding  years,  it  will  be  necessary  to  consider  much  higher  tax  increases  than 
those  used  in  our  1966-67  illustration,  or  to  stage  the  timing  of  additional  pro- 
vincial aid  to  local  government,  or  both. 

23.  But  this  cloud  hovers  over  a  horizon  that  we  shall  not  reach  until  the  next 
section  of  this  chapter.  For  the  moment,  we  can  confine  ourselves  to  the  task  of 
surveying  the  1966  local  scene  under  our  Report.  The  fiscal  effect  on  local 
government  of  all  quantifiable  recommendations  made  in  Volumes  II  and  III, 

270 


Chapter  8:  Paragraphs  21-24 

together  with  a  60  per  cent  level  of  school  grants,  is  depicted  in  Table  8:4.  The 
reduction  in  levy  on  local  property  taxpayers — from  $960  million  to  $648  million — 
is  within  an  eyelash  of  a  full  one-third.  As  to  local  debt  outstanding  at  the  end  of 
the  fiscal  year,  its  ratio  to  P.D.P.  is  one  of  9.5  per  cent.  Later  in  this  Report,  we 
conclude  that  municipal  debt  as  constituted  at  present  should  not  be  permitted  to 
exceed  9  per  cent  of  P.D.P.  We  also  recommend  that  municipalities  be  required 
to  borrow  for  separate  school  boards  as  well  as  other  school  boards.  The  9.5  per 
cent  debt-to-P.D.P.  ratio  shown  in  Table  8:4  is  consistent  with  these  two  measures 
in  that  it  includes  separate  school  debt,  and  comprises  a  level  of  municipal  debt 
which,  if  calculated  on  the  old  basis,  would  have  amounted  to  a  little  less  than 
9.0  per  cent  of  P.D.P.  It  is  therefore  fully  satisfactory. 


Table  8:4 

THE  FISCAL  EFFECT  ON  LOCAL  GOVERNMENTS  FOR   1966, 

ASSUMING  CHANGES  RECOMMENDED  IN  VOLUMES  II  AND  III, 

AND  INCREASED  PROVINCIAL  SCHOOL  GRANTS 

(millions  of  dollars) 

Actual  Tax  Levies  (Estimated)  960 

Deduct: 

Increased  school  grants   136 

Administration  of  justice  15 

New  municipal  unconditional  grant  32 

Other  municipal  grants  (net)  15 

198 
Less  sales  tax  payable  15  183 

Revised  Revenue  Requirements  777 

Deduct: 

Increased  payments  in  lieu  of  tax  34 

Basic  shelter  exemption  grant  95  129 

Revised  Levy  on  Local  Property  Taxpayers  648 

Local  Debt  Outstanding  at  End  of  Fiscal  Year     1,997* 

Deduct: 

Reduction  in  borrowing  because  of  revised  school 
capital  grants   50 

Revised  Local  Debt 1,947 

Provincial  Domestic  Product  20,500 

Revised  local  debt  as  a  per  cent  of  P.D.P 9.5% 

♦Includes  separate  school  debt  of  $162  million. 


24.  We  deem  it  particularly  instructive  at  this  juncture  to  reach  behind  the 
figures  in  Table  8:4  for  a  discussion  of  two  subjects  that  we  have  found  especially 
challenging — school  finance  and  the  general  equity  of  the  property  tax.  Concerning 
the  first,  we  wish  to  emphasize  that  school  grants  at  a  level  of  60  per  cent  of  local 
education  costs  are  not  the  sole  source  of  additional  provincial  aid  we  make  avail- 

271 


Fiscal  Effects  of  the  Recommendations 

able  to  school  boards.  The  provincial  basic  shelter  exemption  grant  contributes  to 
school  board  revenue  because  it  is  payable  on  behalf  of  school  taxes  no  less  than 
municipal.  Again,  school  boards  will  benefit  from  increased  provincial  payments 
in  lieu  of  taxes  proportionately  more  than  municipalities,  in  that  the  latter  have 
heretofore  received  payments  for  which  school  boards  were  ineligible.  The  over-all 
effect  of  our  recommendations  is  therefore  to  give  school  boards  something  like 
two-thirds  of  their  revenue  requirements  from  provincial  sources.  At  the  same  time, 
because  the  basic  school  grant  rate  of  60  per  cent  still  requires  school  boards  on 
average  to  levy  at  a  mill  rate  based  on  40  per  cent  of  their  expenditure,  autonomy 
and  responsibility  are  not  thereby  unduly  endangered, 

25.  With  respect  to  the  equity  of  the  property  tax,  whether  for  municipal 
or  school  purposes,  we  readily  admit  that  a  fiscal  sow's  ear  has  hardly  been 
transformed  into  a  silk  purse.  By  its  very  nature,  the  property  tax  can  never  be 
truly  equitable.  It  must  none  the  less  retain  importance  because  it  is  the  financial 
cornerstone  of  local  goverimient.  We  believe  that,  under  our  recommendations,  the 
property  tax  can  henceforth  survive  with  appreciably  reduced  inequity.  This  is 
not  simply  because  less  revenue  will  be  required  of  it.  More  especially,  the  effect 
of  the  basic  shelter  exemption  grant  is  to  make  available  proportionately  more  tax 
reUef  where  it  is  most  needed.  Indeed,  on  residential  properties  with  the  lowest 
market  values,  up  to  50  per  cent  of  the  tax  may  be  removed  from  the  owners  or 
occupants.  The  most  harshly  regressive  aspects  of  the  tax  are  thereby  substantially 
mitigated. 

THE  FISCAL  SCENE:    1968-75 

26.  Departing  now  from  our  1966-67  statistical  exercise,  we  shift  to  the  period 
1968-75.  This  shift  is  of  immense  practical  importance  because,  after  all,  our 
recommendations  can  be  implemented  only  in  the  future.  But  it  necessitates 
considerable  sacrifices  in  accuracy.  The  calculation  of  the  effect  of  our  recom- 
mendations, which  for  1966-67  was  a  matter  of  departing  largely  from  actual  data, 
now  involves  pihng  estimates  on  projections  which  are  themselves  estimates.  These 
projections  were  completed  during  the  summer  of  1966  and  were  of  necessity 
based  on  the  information  available  in  that  time.  They  accordingly  do  not  take 
account  of  certain  new  developments,  such  as  the  recent  federal-provmcial  arrange- 
ments for  the  financing  of  post-secondary  education  and  the  accompanying  size  of 
provincial  expenditure  commitments  to  community  colleges.  Nor  are  they  based 
on  economic  conditions  as  buoyant  as  those  that  have  in  fact  materialized. 

27.  In  making  our  projections,  we  were  concerned  with  general  trends  over  a 
longer  period  rather  than  with  the  circumstances  of  any  one  year.  We  assumed  that 
the  economy,  which  was  in  a  highly  prosperous  condition  in  1 966,  would  experience 
some  slowing  down  in  its  rate  of  expansion  and  would  return  to  the  projected  level 
of  P.D.P.  by  1969.  Thereafter,  we  assumed  that  fluctuations  would  occur  around 
the  projected  values. 

28.  As  we  consider  the  position  a  year  later  it  appears  that  the  P.D.P.,  barring 

272 


Chapter  8:  Paragraphs  25-31 

a  more  serious  recession  than  we  think  at  all  probable  in  the  light  of  post-war 
experience,  is  likely  to  be  somewhat  above  the  value  we  projected  for  the  next 
few  years.  What  is  the  effect  on  our  projections  of  government  revenue,  expendi- 
ture and  debt  of  a  level  of  P.D.P.  that  exceeds  the  value  we  projected  for  it? 

29.  It  is  immediately  obvious  that  if  P.D.P.  or  income  is  higher  than  we  had 
expected,  then,  with  a  given  level  of  tax  rates,  government  revenues,  especially 
those  of  the  Province,  will  also  be  higher  than  we  had  projected.  But  it  is  also  true 
that  in  a  more  prosperous  period  costs  are  hkely  to  be  higher  than  they  would  have 
been  otherwise.  On  balance  we  would  expect  that  the  gain  in  revenue  when  the 
economy  is  more  prosperous  than  projected  would  be  somewhat  greater  than  the 
increase  in  expenditure,  but  what  is  clear  is  that  there  are  forces  pulling  in  both 
directions  and  no  definite  statement  can  be  made  as  to  which  one  will  dominate. 
We  are  of  the  view  that,  if  the  economy  of  the  Province  for  the  next  few  years  is 
somewhat  more  prosperous  than  we  had  projected,  the  scale  of  revenue,  expendi- 
ture and  debt  will  be  changed,  but  we  would  not  expect  any  striking  change  in  the 
proportion  they  bear  to  one  another,  and  to  P.D.P.^ 

30.  Bearing  in  mind  the  difficulty  of  the  exercise,  we  have  chosen  to  illustrate 
the  statistical  dimension  of  the  measures  we  contemplate  in  only  three  of  the  seven 
fiscal  years  that  span  the  period  1968-75.  The  first,  1968-69,  is  the  earliest  in 
which  any  of  our  recommendations  could  begin  to  take  hold.  The  second,  1971-72, 
is  the  middle  year  in  the  time  period  under  discussion.  The  third,  1974-75,  is  also 
the  last  in  the  period  and  as  such  enables  us  to  sketch  a  scene  that  takes  cumulative 
account  of  all  statistically  predictable  developments. 

31.  Our  exercise  begins  with  T-able  8:5.  This  Table  shows,  for  each  of  the 
years  under  discussion,  projected  provincial  expenditures  and  revenues  before  and 
after  the  recommendations  made  in  Volumes  II  and  III,  including  provision  for 
higher  school  grants.  Figures  for  1968-69  appear  in  two  columns,  A  and  B,  of 
which  the  former  assumes  full  implementation  of  all  items  of  additional  aid  to  local 
government,  and  the  latter  involves  a  phased  approach  to  be  discussed  shortly. 
Item  7,  the  most  important  line  in  the  Table,  shows  the  projected  deficit  after  the 
revenue  recommendations  in  Volumes  II  and  III  but  before  tax  rate  changes. 
These  deficits  are,  for  1968-69,  $598  million  (column  A)  and  $533  million 
(column  B),  for  1971-72  $819  million,  and  for  1974-75  $1,123  mUlion.  The 
staggering  magnitude  of  these  amounts,  so  much  greater  than  the  $385  million 
with  which  we  attempted  to  cope  in  our  1966-67  exercise,  is  due  in  large  part  to  the 
widening  provincial  revenue-expenditure  gap  projected  in  our  forecast,  a  gap  that 
haunts  the  fiscal  scene  with  or  without  our  recommendations. 


^Recent  experience  with  the  provincial  accounts  gives  us  some  small  encouragement  on 
this  score.  The  1967-68  provincial  revenue  and  expenditure  estimates  as  given  in  the 
1967  provincial  budget  are  both  substantially  higher  than  our  projection  of  these  items, 
as  would  indeed  be  expected  in  a  prosperous  period.  But  the  increase  in  the  net  capital 
debt  of  the  Province  as  estimated  by  the  Provincial  Treasurer  is  $162  million,  while 
our  projected  figure  adjusted  to  the  provincial  accounts  basis  is  $161  million. 

273 


Fiscal  Effects  of  the  Recommendations 

Table  8:5 

PROJECTED  PROVINCIAL  DEFICIT  AFTER  RECOMMENDATIONS,  INCLUDING 

PROVISION  FOR  HIGHER  SCHOOL  GRANTS,  BUT  BEFORE  TAX  RATE 

CHANGES,  IN  SELECTED  FISCAL  YEARS   1968-75 

(millions  of  dollars) 


1968-69         1968-69 

A  B  1971-72         1974-75 

1.  Projected  provincial  expenditure 

before    recommendations*    2,280  2,280  2,820  3,569 

2.  Additional   provincial  expenditures  after 
recommendations,  including  provision  for 

higher  school  grants  390  325  441  500 

3.  Total    projected    provincial    expenditures 
after  recommendations,  including 

provision  for  higher  school  grants  2,670  2,605  3,261  4,069 

4.  Projected  provincial  revenue  before 

recommendations   1,925  1,925  2,265  2,724 

5.  Additional  provincial  revenue  from 
recommendations  made  in  Volumes 

II  and  III  147  147  177  222 

6.  Provincial  revenue  after 
recommendations  made  in  Volumes 

II  and  III  2,072  2,072  2,442  2,946 

7.  Projected  deficit  before  requisite  tax 

rate  changes  598  533  819  1,123 

*The  projected  expenditure  figures  for  each  of  the  years  shown  are  lower  than  those  originally 
projected  in  Chapter  6  by  $10  million  in  1968-69,  $66  million  in  1971-72  and  $153  million  in 
1974-75.  Each  of  these  figures  represents  reductions  in  interest  payments.  The  1968-69 
adjustment  is  necessitated  by  the  fact  that  economic  conditions  more  buoyant  than  those 
originally  forecast  will  have  resulted  in  an  outstanding  debt  at  the  beginning  of  that  year 
lower  than  the  one  originally  projected  by  us.  As  to  1971-72  and  1974-75,  interest  reductions 
are  necessary  because  of  the  cumulative  effect  of  the  revenue  measures  we  develop  later  in 
this  chapter.  We  assume  that  these  measures  are  allowed  to  take  hold  in  such  manner  that 
the  debt  outstanding  in  any  given  year  during  the  period  under  consideration  has  been  held 
in  a  constant  relation  to  P.D.P.,  thereby  reducing  the  interest  load  in  subsequent  years. 

32.  Facing  as  we  do  clearly  unacceptable  deficits,  we  indicate  in  Tables  8:6 
and  8:7  the  outcome  of  a  quest  for  requisite  tax  rate  increases  whose  additional 
yield  could  reduce  the  deficits  to  tolerable  size.  Table  8:6  shows  tax  increases 
over  1967  levels  for  each  of  nine  revenue  fields  in  the  years  under  discussion, 
together  with  their  resulting  yields.  Its  companion  Table,  8:7,  lists  the  over-all 
provincial  tax  rates  that  would  be  applicable  under  the  contemplated  increases. 
Because  of  their  complicated  structure,  it  is  impracticable  to  devise,  for  Table  8:7, 
the  applicable  rates  of  liquor  mark-up,  tobacco  tax  and  succession  duty. 

33.  Concentrating  first  on  the  year  1968-69,  we  begin  by  introducing  personal 
income  and  sales  tax  increases  similar  to  the  ones  contemplated  in  our  1966-67 
exercise.  These  increases  are  8  per  cent  on  the  federal  basic  tax,  bringing  the 
provincial  personal  income  tax  rate  to  36  per  cent,  and  1  per  cent  on  sales  for  an 
over-all  tax  of  6  per  cent.  They  are  subject  to  the  same  comments  as  were  made  in 
the  context  of   1966-67   and  involve  the  maximum  change  we  deem  tolerable 

274 


Chapter  8:  Paragraphs  32-33 
Table  8:6 

TAX  RATE  CHANGES  REQUIRED  TO  COPE  WITH  DEFICITS  PROJECTED  IN 

TABLE  8:5 

(dollar  figures  in  millions) 

Cumulative  Tax  Increase  Over  1967  and  Resulting  Revenue  Yield 

1968-69  1971-72  1974-75 

Cum.  tax  Cum.  tax  Cum.  tax 

increase         Yield        increase         Yield        increase         Yield 

Personal  income  tax — 
additional  percentage 
points  applicable  to 
federal  basic  tax  8%  $144  10%  $210  12%  $324 

Sales  tax — additional 
percentage  points 
applicable  to  sales  1%  113  2%  264  2%  320 

Gasoline  and  motor  fuels 

taxes— additional  cents  ^4  gas  3^  gas  M  gas 

per  gallon 2.7^  other  40        4<t  other  66        4<f  other  72 

Corporation  income  tax — 
additional  percentage 
applicable  to  taxable 
incomes    1%  27  1%  31  3%  111 

Liquor  profits — percentage 

increase  in  sales  prices  ....       5%  30  5%  35  7%  60 

Insurance  premiums  tax — 
additional  percentage 
points  applicable  to 
premiums   nil  nil  1%  12  1%  15 

Tobacco  tax — increase  in 

level  of  tax nil  nil  '/a  8  Vs  9 

Succession  duties — increase 

in  level  of  tax  nil  nil  10%  11  10%  14 

Mines  profits  tax — increase 
in  percentage  points 
applicable  to  mines 
profits   nil  nil  nil  nil  3%  6 

Total  Yield  from 

Tax  Rate  Changes $354 $637 $931 

in  a  single  year.  But  given  the  magnitude  of  the  1968-69  deficit,  we  are  forced 
to  seek  still  greater  revenue  elsewhere.  We  consider  motor  vehicle  fuel  taxes  to  be 
the  strongest  candidate.  This  is  because,  under  our  equity  rule  that  road-user  taxes 
should  finance  between  65  and  75  per  cent  of  road  expenditures,  there  is  room  within 
the  ceiUng  of  the  range  for  a  20  rise  in  the  gasoline  tax,  10  more  than  we  would 
have  utilized  in  1966-67,  accompanied  by  a  proportional  increase  in  diesel-fuel  tax. 
Where  fiscal  requirements  are  large,  we  deem  it  reasonable  that  the  revenues  con- 
tributed by  road  users  should  be  at  the  top  of  the  range  permitted  by  the  benefits 
principle. 

275 


Fiscal  Effects  of  the  Recommendations 

Table  8:7 

RATES  OF  TAX*  THAT  WOULD  BE  IN  EFFECT  AFTER  RATE  CHANGES, 
COMPARED  TO  ACTUAL  RATES  AS  OF  JANUARY  1,   1967 

Jan.  1,  1967     1968-69         1971-72         1974-75 

Personal  income  taxf 

Rate  applicable  to  federal  basic  tax  28%  36%  38%  40% 

Sales  tax 

Rate  applicable  to  sales  5%  6%  7%  7% 

Gasoline  and  other  motor  fuel  taxes  ,.^  lo-*  m,*  m^ 

Rate  per  gallon  ^^^  ^as  18<f  gas  19<f  gas  19<f  gas 

Kaie  per  gaiion  22<J  other     24.7<f  other    26(f  other      26^  other 

Corporation  income  tax 

Rate  applicable  to  incomes  12%  13%  13%  15% 

Insurance  premiums  tax 

Rate  applicable  to  premiums  2%  2%  3%  3% 

Mines  profits  tax 

Rate  applicable  to  mines  profits  12%  12%  12%  15% 

♦This  Table  omits  three  revenue  sources — the  tobacco  tax,  liquor  profits  and  succession 
duties.  The  tobacco  tax  is  excluded  because  it  applies  at  variable  rates  and  is  therefore  too 
complicated  for  summary  presentation.  The  other  two  revenue  sources  would  be  restructured 
under  recommendations  made  in  this  Report;  their  rates  are  therefore  not  subject  to  simple 
tabular  comparison  with  those  in  effect  in  1967. 

tThe  personal  income  tax  rate  was  increased  by  4  percentage  points,  and  the  corporation 
income  tax  rate  by  1  percentage  point  effective  January  1,  1967.  At  this  time  the  federal 
government  increased  its  abatement  correspondingly  as  a  result  of  revised  arrangements  for 
sharing  post-secondary  education  costs. 

34.  Unfortunately,  there  is  no  escaping  yet  further  provincial  tax  increases 
under  our  projections  for  1968-69  if  net  capital  debt,  which  we  shall  examine 
momentarily,  is  to  be  within  hailing  distance  of  9  per  cent  of  P.D.P.  Drawing  only 
the  coldest  comfort  from  the  unlikely  prospect  that  1968  might  be  a  year  of  such 
magnificent  prosperity  as  to  preclude  the  need,  we  hesitantly  draw  on  the  corpora- 
tion income  tax  and  on  liquor  profits.  An  extra  1  percentage  point  on  corporate 
income,  bringing  the  Ontario  tax  rate  to  13,  coupled  with  a  rise  in  the  liquor 
mark-up  equivalent  to  a  5  per  cent  increase  in  sales  price,  yields  an  additional  $57 
million.  Added  to  the  sum  produced  by  the  personal  income,  sales  and  motor 
vehicle  tax  changes,  the  result  is  the  $354  million  appearing  at  the  bottom  of 
Table  8:6.  As  to  our  reluctance  at  tapping  the  corporation  income  tax  and  liquor 
profits,  we  simply  refer  back  to  our  comments  in  the  context  of  1966-67  and  post- 
pone further  discussion  to  the  final  section  of  this  chapter. 

35.  We  now  press  on  to  1971-72  and  1974-75.  As  a  preliminary  point,  we 
must  unhappily  report  that  the  scene  is  even  darker  than  it  appears  in  the  Tables. 
Whereas,  in  1968-69,  the  Province  could  have  realized  a  tolerable  deficit  simply 
by  effecting  in  that  year  the  revenue  changes  we  depict,  the  same  is  not  true  of 
either  1971-72  or  1974-75.  Because  our  projected  expenditure-revenue  gap  widens 
annually,  it  requires  modification  that  is  likewise  annual.  Accordingly,  of  the  tax 
increases  we  show  for  1971-72  and  1974-75,  some  will  have  had  to  be  made  in 

276 


Chapter  8:  Paragraphs  34-38 

earlier  years.  If  they  have  not,  then  the  1971-72  and  1974-75  gaps  will  be  that 
much  larger  and  would  require  at  those  times  even  greater  increases  than  the 
ones  shown. 

36.  With  this  ominous  observation  in  mind,  we  can  summarize  the  requisite 
tax  changes  as  follows.  By  1971-72,  the  personal  income  tax  would  have  had 
to  reach  38  per  cent  of  the  federal  basic  tax,  and  to  have  increased  further  to  40 
per  cent  by  1974-75.  Sales  and  gasoline  taxes,  after  rising  again  by  1971-72  to  7 
per  cent  and  190  respectively,  could  remain  unchanged  for  the  rest  of  the  period. 
Though  the  corporation  income  tax  and  liquor  profits  could  maintain  their  1968-69 
levels  through  1971-72,  additional  increases  would  have  to  materialize  sub- 
sequently, resulting  in  a  15  per  cent  corporate  tax  and  liquor  prices  7  per  cent 
above  existing  levels.  For  the  rest,  we  envisage  a  3  rather  than  2  per  cent  insurance 
premiums  tax,  a  one-third  increase  in  the  tobacco  tax  and  the  equivalent  of  a  10  per 
cent  adjustment  in  succession  duties,  all  by  1971-72.  A  3  per  cent  boost  in  the 
mines  profits  tax  could  be  postponed  to  1974-75. 

37.  In  that  we  envisage  increases  ultimately  affecting  virtually  every  revenue 
source  in  Ontario,  we  must  stress  that  our  prime  consideration  is  equity,  not 
expediency.  In  equity,  no  tax  can  be  completely  isolated  from  the  fiscal  system  of 
which  it  is  part.  Thus,  to  take  a  few  examples,  additional  taxes  on  personal  income 
must  eventually  call  for  an  upward  revision  in  the  taxation  of  wealth,  of  which 
succession  duties  constitute  the  key  form.  There  also  comes  a  point  where  the  tax 
on  corporation  income  must  be  reconsidered  in  the  light  of  that  on  personal  income. 
Again,  if  the  retail  sales  tax  is  rising,  so  should  taxes  on  tobacco  and  insurance 
premiums,  which  stand  in  lieu  of  sales  tax.  If  we  therefore  advocate  increases  widely 
dispersed  among  tax  fields,  this  is  the  result  of  our  concern  for  an  equitable  and 
balanced  fiscal  system,  not  the  outcome  of  a  simple  grapeshot  approach. 

38.  We  now  carry  the  revenues  yielded  by  our  exercise,  $637  million  in  1971-72 
and  $931  million  in  1974-75,  together  with  the  $354  miUion  obtained  in  1968-69,  to 
Table  8:8.  Here  our  increases  can  be  seen  to  reduce  the  projected  deficit  to  a  size 
that  leaves  net  capital  debt,  after  allowing  an  adjustment  for  the  new  school 
capital  grant,"  at  exactly  9  per  cent  of  P.D.P.  in  each  of  1971-72  and  1974-75, 
but  above  this  ratio  in  1968-69.  The  reader  will  note  that,  as  in  Table  8:5,  we 
present  data  for  1968-69  under  two  columns,  A  and  B,  of  which  the  first  assumes 
immediate  implementation  of  all  contemplated  assistance  to  local  government, 
and  the  second  a  phased  approach.  When  stated  in  terms  of  the  relation  between 
debt  and  P.D.P.,  the  two  approaches  yield  ratios  of  9.8  and  9.5  per  cent 
respectively. 


*This  particular  adjustment  declines  steadily  in  value  because  it  is  warranted  only  in  the 
transitional  period  during  which  the  Province  simultaneously  finances  the  capital  out- 
lays of  school  boards  at  the  time  they  are  made  and  continues  to  make  grants  on  debt 
charges  locally  incurred  prior  to  the  year  of  implementation.  No  adjustment  will  be 
called  for  once  all  school  debt  contracted  prior  to  the  year  of  implementation  has  been 
retired;  in  the  meantime,  the  adjustment  gradually  declines  with  each  succeeding 
retirement  of  "old"  school  debt. 

277 


Fiscal  Effects  of  the  Recommendations 

39.  If  we  are  willing  to  countenance,  in  1968-69,  debt  ratios  substantially 
above  9  per  cent,  it  is  because  we  believe  that  our  tax  rate  changes  for  that  year 
lie  at  the  outside  limits  of  tolerance.  Even  after  substantially  increased  use  of 
personal  income  and  consumption  taxes,  we  are  forced  to  have  recourse  to  the 
economic  uncertainties  of  an  increase  in  corporate  income  tax.  Going  still 
further,  we  have  not  only  violated  the  principle  of  neutrality  in  the  taxation  of 
consumption  by  singling  out  liquor  for  a  price  rise  but,  in  that  liquor  prices  wUl 
themselves  be  subject  to  the  higher  retail  sales  tax,  we  have  countenanced  what  is 
in  effect  a  double  tax  increase.  Under  such  circumstances,  we  find  ourselves 
forced  to  concede  the  necessity  for  a  debt  ratio  in  excess  of  9  per  cent,  but  as 
between  the  levels  of  9.8  and  9.5  per  cent,  the  latter  is  clearly  preferable.  We  note 
in  this  context  that  while  the  difference  between  the  two  ratios  of  only  0.3  per 
cent  may  appear  almost  marginal,  expenditure  commitments  of  no  less  than  $65 
million  are  involved. 

40.  Fortunately,  the  case  for  restraint  that  is  indicated  by  revenue  and  debt 
levels  also  beckons  in  the  light  of  a  rational  approach  to  the  grants  we  recommend. 
To  be  sure,  most  of  these  grants  do  not,  in  our  view,  lend  themselves  to  a  policy 
of  gradual  introduction.  Thus  we  would  be  loath  to  advocate  phased  implementa- 
tion of  our  basic  shelter  exemption  grant,  because  this  subsidy  brings  relief  where 
it  is  most  needed.  Provincial  payments  in  lieu  of  tax,  for  their  part,  will  close  what 
has  been  an  all  but  inexcusable  loophole  in  the  property  tax  base.  The  full  amount 
of  our  new  unconditional  grant  to  municipalities  is  necessary  to  abolish  the  split 
mill  rate.  School  grants,  however,  are  another  matter.  Here  we  find  a  convincing 
case  for  gradual  implementation,  one  arising  from  our  very  recommendations  on 
the  subject. 

41.  In  the  chapter  we  devote  to  school  finance,  we  espouse  a  number  of 
complex  adjustments  in  the  school  grant  structure.  Time  is  required,  by  the 
responsible  provincial  authorities  no  less  than  by  the  local  school  boards,  to  give 
effect  to  these  measures.  Furthermore,  it  is  most  desirable  to  ensure  that  major 
structural  changes  be  accompanied  by  a  rising  level  of  aid  that  will  ease  the  impact 
of  adjustment. 

42.  With  ample  justification  on  grounds  of  debt,  tax  and  grant  policy,  we 
accordingly  urge  that  the  government  achieve  the  60  per  cent  level  of  school  aid 
we  envisage  through  deliberate  staging.  From  their  present  average  level  of  about 
45  per  cent,  the  grants  should  take  their  sharpest  rise  at  the  outset  because  of  the 
revenue  effects  of  abolishing  the  split  mill  rate  for  school  as  well  as  municipal 
purposes.  We  estimate  that  a  first  year  average  rate  of  52  per  cent  is  sufficient  to 
meet  our  objectives  equitably,  and  it  is  on  this  basis  that  the  grants  were  calculated 
for  column  B  of  Tables  8:5  and  8:8.  Thereafter  the  grants  might  be  allowed  to 
reach  a  56  per  cent  level  in  the  second  year,  and  should  attain  their  full  60  per 
cent  average  in  the  third  year.  Accordingly,  we  recommend  that: 

The  Province  raise  the  average  level  of  education  grants  to         8:1 
60  per  cent  of  school  board  expenditure  over  a  three-year 
period. 

278 


Chapter  8:  Paragraphs  39-43 

Table  8:8 

PROJECTED  PROVINCIAL  DEFICIT  BEFORE  AND  AFTER  TAX  RATE 
CHANGES,  AND  RESULTING  NET  CAPITAL  DEBT  POSITION 

(millions  of  dollars) 

1968-69         1968-69 

A  B  1971-72         1974-75 

Projected  deficit  before  tax  rate  changes 

(Table  8:5)    598  533  819  1,123 

Deduct  additional  yield  from  tax  rate 
changes  (Table  8:6)  354  354  637  931 

Projected  deficit  after  tax  rate  changes 244  179  182  192 

Add  projected  net  capital  debt  at 

beginning  of  fiscal  year  1,926  1,926  2,124  2,547 

Projected  net  capital  debt  at  end  of 
fiscal  year  after  tax  rate  changes  2,170  2,105  2,306  2,739 

Deduct  allowance  for  new  school 
capital  grants  60  52  45  30 

Projected  net  capital  debt  at  end  of  fiscal 
year  after  tax  rate  changes  and  allowance 
for  new  school  capital  grants  2,110  2,053  2,261  2,709 

P.D.P 21,600  21,600  25,000  30,000 

Projected  net  capital  debt  as  a  percentage  of 
P.D.P 9.8%  9.5%  9.0%  9.0% 


43.  With  the  above  recommendation,  we  can  complete  our  statistical  sketch 
by  addressing  ourselves  to  Tables  8:9  and  8:10.  Table  8:9  simply  records  projected 
local  expenditure,  revenue  and  debt  under  this  Report,  including  separate  school 
debt.  Its  companion  Table  sets  forth  the  degree  of  relief  accorded  to  local  property 
taxpayers.    As  the  latter  shows,  under  a  phased  implementation  of  school  grants, 

Table  8:9 

LOCAL  EXPENDITURE,  REVENUE  AND  DEBT  POSITION, 
ASSUMING  IMPLEMENTATION  OF  THE  RECOMMENDATIONS 

(millions  of  dollars) 

1968  1971  1974 

Expenditure    after    recommendations    2,028  2,504  3,086 

Deduct  revenues  after  recommendations  1,968  2,384  2,926 

Additions   to  debt    60  120  160 

Debt  at  end  of  fiscal  year*  2,120  2,440  2,920 

P.D.P 21,600  25,000  30,000 

Debt  as  a  percentage  of  P.D.P.t  9.8%  9.8%  9.7% 

*Debt  figures  are  reduced  to  take  account  of  school  capital  debt  to  be  assumed  by  the 
Province  under  the  recommendations. 

tDebt  includes  separate  school  debt  as  under  our  recommendations  municipalities  would 
borrow  for  separate  school  boards.  Debt,  excluding  separate  school  debt,  as  a  percentage 
of  P.D.P.  would  be  9  per  cent  for  each  of  the  three  years. 

279 


Fiscal  Effects  of  the  Recommendations 

Table  8:10 

EFFECTIVE  LEVY  ON  LOCAL  PROPERTY  TAXPAYERS,  ASSUMING 
IMPLEMENTATION  OF  THE  RECOMMENDATIONS  AS  A  PERCENTAGE 

OF  PROJECTED  TAX 

{millions  of  dollars) 

1968  1971  1974 

Projected  tax  levies  before  recommendations  1,099  1,387  1,748 

Deduct  additional  provincial  payments 

under  recommendations*  255  374  435 


Effective  levy  on  local  property  taxpayers  844  1,013  1,313 


Effective  levy  as  a  per  cent  of  projected  levy  76.8%        73.0%        75.1% 

*  Excluding  school  capital  grants. 

the  effective  local  tax  levy  in  1968  plummets  to  only  slightly  more  than  three- 
quarters  of  the  level  it  would  otherwise  reach.  By  1971  when  the  school  grants 
are  completely  implemented,  it  is  even  lower.  But  the  reader  will  observe  that 
countervailing  forces  are  at  work.  The  full  effect  of  our  recommendations  in  1971 
is  an  effective  levy  of  73  per  cent  of  the  projected  levy,  whereas,  in  the  exercise  we 
undertook  on  the  basis  of  1966  data,  it  was  within  a  small  margin  of  two-thirds. 
Furthermore,  our  projections  include  a  moderate  annual  rise  in  the  property  tax  of 
1  mill.  This  rise  will  become  apparent  on  every  tax  bill  from  the  time  all  new 
grants  are  fully  in  effect.  By  1974,  the  effective  levy  as  a  percentage  of  the 
projected  levy  has  indeed  begun  to  rise.  The  reason  is  as  simple  as  the  classic  fiscal 
story  of  local  government.  The  natural  forces  at  work  on  local  expenditures  out- 
strip the  elasticity  of  their  revenue  sources,  including  some  that  we  ourselves  have 
devised.  This  is  particularly  so  of  our  new  unconditional  grant,  which  is  tied  to 
population  and  is  impervious  to  rising  local  costs.  It  is  true  as  well  of  our  basic 
shelter  exemption  grant,  which  does  not  take  into  account  higher  levels  of  market 
value.  All  of  this  argues  for  the  need  to  keep  the  local  fiscal  scene  under  continued 
surveillance,  as  we  recommend  in  this  Report.  It  also  underlines  the  fact  that  the 
provincial  tax  increases  we  suggest  do  not  by  any  means  imply  that  the  property 
tax  will  itself  be  exempt  from  the  pressures  on  the  fiscal  system.  Accordingly,  there 
may  well  be  a  need  for  an  upward  revision  in  the  level  of  grants  we  recommend 
before  the  period  under  discussion  ends,  and  this  even  in  the  light  of  the  drastic 
income  and  consumption  tax  increases  the  Province  will  already  have  been  called 
upon  to  make. 

THE  FISCAL  SCENE:   CONCLUDING  COMMENTS 

44.  In  closing  this  chapter,  we  wish  first  to  remind  the  reader  that  its  exposition 
is  confined  to  those  of  our  recommendations  whose  impact  is  direct  and  quantifi- 
able. The  remainder  are  no  less  important,  whether  from  the  viewpoint  of  equity, 
efficiency  or  economic  growth.  Not  the  least  of  their  virtues  is  that  they  can 
substantially  mitigate  the  harsh  effects  of  the  provincial  tax  increases  we  envisage. 

280 


Chapter  8:  Paragraphs  44-47 

45.  We  are  duty  bound,  of  course,  to  comment  at  some  length  on  the  size  of 
these  increases.  First,  their  size  demonstrates  in  stark  terms  the  magnitude  of  the 
revenue  problem  that  faces  the  Province  of  Ontario.  Second,  they  are  meant  to 
illustrate  the  manner  in  which  we  would  distribute  tax  increases  in  the  future,  that 
is,  to  indicate  the  relative  emphasis  upon  the  various  tax  and  other  revenue  sources 
we  think  it  most  appropriate  to  adopt.  Third  and  finally,  they  generate  important 
consequences  both  for  the  structure  of  taxation  and  for  federal-provincial 
negotiation. 

46.  Concerning  this  problem  of  the  sharp  increases  in  the  prospective  magni- 
tude of  Ontario's  expenditure-revenue  gap,  we  face  a  situation  whose  gravity  is 
not  to  be  underestimated.  We  emphasize  that  the  tax  increases  that  we  have 
projected  are  based  only  on  the  needs  generated  by  the  expenditure  programs  to 
which  provincial  and  local  governments  were  committed  at  the  time  we  made  our 
projections.  While  these  projections  cannot  take  account  of  possible  future 
economies  that  would  reduce  the  cost  of  present  programs,  we  find  it  reasonable 
to  assume  that  any  new  expenditure  commitments  in  the  period  under  review  will 
involve  either  equivalent  additional  taxation  or  recourse  to  additional  debt.  As  to 
the  latter,  the  debt  policy  we  espouse  is  in  fact  not  so  rigid  as  to  preclude  a  secular 
rise  in  provincial  debt  that  would  result  in  debt  ratios  moderately  above  9  per  cent 
of  P.D.P.  However,  we  have  felt  bound  to  apply  the  9  per  cent  rule  with  reason- 
able stringency  in  developing  prospective  tax  increases  precisely  because  our 
expenditure  projections  cannot  take  account  of  possible  new  programs.  We  have 
no  mandate  to  comment  on  government  expenditure,  but  we  must  point  out  that 
even  the  tax  levels  that  we  have  been  compelled  to  contemplate  give  us  serious 
concern  about  whether  the  resulting  revenue  system  would  be  "as  conducive  to  the 
sound  growth  of  the  Province  as  can  be  devised".  The  searching  scrutiny  that 
should  accordingly  be  given  to  any  new  spending  programs  is  therefore  obvious, 
as  is  the  need  to  ensure  that  existing  expenditures  are  efficient  and  equitable. 

47.  As  to  the  relative  weight  we  place  on  different  taxes  in  our  illustrative 
increases,  what  we  depict  is  the  kind  of  balance  we  deem  advisable  in  meeting 
through  taxation  the  sharply  rising  demands  on  the  Ontario  revenue  system. 
Having  drastically  reduced  the  burden  of  the  property  tax,  we  weight  most  heavily 
taxes  on  income  and  consumption,  recognizing  their  superiority  in  equity,  clarity 
and  simplicity.  But  we  also  recognize  that  taxes  are  often  inter-related,  and  that 
hence,  to  take  an  example,  higher  taxes  on  personal  income  legitimately  call  for  a 
reconsideration  of  succession  duties.  We  are  therefore  reasonably  satisfied  with 
the  balance  exhibited  by  our  revenue  pattern.  Nevertheless,  we  are  concerned 
about  the  use  of  the  corporate  income  tax,  which  must  be  considered  most  care- 
fully in  terms  of  its  economic  consequences.  In  particular,  because  of  its  possible 
effects  on  the  competitive  position  of  Ontario  firms,  the  corporate  income  tax 
should  at  all  times  be  set,  if  not  at  precisely  comparable  levels,  at  least  with  due 
regard  to  the  levels  of  corporate  taxation  that  prevail  in  other  jurisdictions, 
foreign  as  well  as  Canadian. 

281 


Fiscal  Effects  of  the  Recommendations 

48.  With  this  reservation  duly  noted,  we  believe  that,  in  meeting  its  future 
revenue  requirements  through  taxation,  the  Province  should  follow  the  pattern 
of  relative  weights  that  our  tax  increases  indicate.    We  therefore  recommend  that: 

To  the  extent  that  higher  provincial  taxation  will  be  needed         8:2 
to  meet  future  revenue  requirements^  the  Province  employ 
a  carefully   balanced  combination   of   increases   in   income, 
consumption  and  wealth  taxes  designed  to  take  account  of 
the  considerations  made  explicit  in  this  Report. 

49.  Finally,  there  are  the  twin  questions  of  tax  structure  and  federal-provincial 
affairs.  Nowhere  are  these  more  closely  intertwined  than  in  the  personal  income 
tax.  Here  the  need  for  a  drastic  overhaul  in  rate  structure  is  imperative.  Thus,  for 
example,  when  we  reluctantly  add  12  percentage  points  to  the  provincial  personal 
income  tax,  we  produce  combined  federal  and  provincial  tax  that  is  nothing  less 
than  a  confiscatory  tax  in  the  higher  rate  brackets.  To  illustrate,  the  top  combined 
marginal  rate  at  present,  84  per  cent  on  foreign  investment  income,  becomes  one 
of  94  per  cent.  Quite  aside,  therefore,  from  the  question  of  additional  federal 
abatement,  there  is  an  urgent  need  to  revise  personal  income  tax  rates  if  only  to 
enable  the  provinces  to  levy  additional  taxes  of  their  own.  We  note,  in  this 
context,  that  the  top  effective  rate  of  any  tax  must  always  be  a  matter  of  special 
concern.  The  new  system  of  succession  duties  we  recommend,  for  instance,  involves 
a  progressive  rate  scheme  whose  top  bracket  has  been  set  at  a  level  that,  under  any 
equity  rule,  leaves  less  room  for  increases  than  those  below. 

50.  The  Government  of  Ontario  should  therefore  be  in  the  forefront  of  those 
who  advocate  a  revision  of  the  personal  income  tax  schedule.  For  the  rest,  this 
Report  builds  a  clear-cut  case  for  three  categories  of  revisions  in  federal-provincial 
revenue  arrangements.  Those  in  the  first  category  aim  principally  at  enhancing 
the  simplicity  of  the  tax  system  and  the  structural  integrity  of  collection  arrange- 
ments. Here  we  advocate,  for  reasons  stated  in  Volume  III,  that  the  federal  gov- 
ernment vacate  the  succession  duty  field,  that  it  allow  provincial  sharing  in  the 
yield  of  the  non-resident  withholding  tax,  and  that  it  recognize  that  its  special 
corporate  surplus  distribution  taxes  reduce  the  base  on  which  the  provinces  levy 
personal  income  tax. 

51.  The  revisions  in  the  second  category  involve  increased  federal  abatement 
in  lieu  of  existing  shared-cost  programs.  There  is  an  exceedingly  strong  case  for 
such  abatements,  which  we  develop  at  length  in  this  Report.  But  we  feel  bound 
to  point  out,  in  the  context  of  the  evident  magnitude  of  the  Province's  financial 
problems,  that  tax  room  in  lieu  of  existing  shared-cost  programs  should  not  be 
made  at  the  expense  of  further  unencumbered  abatement  in  federal  taxes. 

52.  This  brings  us  to  the  third  and  last  category  of  revisions  in  federal- 
provincial  arrangements:  the  necessity  for  unencumbered  additional  tax  abate- 
ments to  the  Province.  Such  abatements  are  clearly  indispensable  if  the  Canadian 
fiscal  system  is  to  provide  an  equitable  and  rational  means  of  financing  the  enormous 
revenue  requirements  incurred  by  the  provincial  governments   in  the  course  of 

282 


Chapter  8:  Paragraphs  48-54 

providing  ever-rising  levels  of  public  services  that  fall  within  their  constitutional 
jurisdiction.  In  that  we  have  already  stressed  this  financial  need  at  great  length, 
we  shall  only  summarize  a  few  of  the  guiding  principles  we  develop  in  other 
chapters.  Since  the  personal  income  tax  has  greater  elasticity  than  any  other 
revenue  field,  there  can  be  no  doubt  that  abatement  points  on  this  tax  are  to  be 
preferred  over  all  others  by  Ontario.  The  only  limit  that  we  detect  in  principle  on 
the  abatement  of  this  tax  is  the  point  beyond  which  federal  capacity  to  shoulder 
overriding  responsibility  for  economic  stabilization  policy  would  be  endangered. 
Precisely  where  this  point  is  reached  is  in  no  small  part  a  function  of  the  effective- 
ness of  federal-provincial  co-ordination  in  economic  matters,  but  we  think  that 
in  any  event  this  point  lies  somewhat  beyond  the  50  per  cent  abatement  level 
frequently  cited  as  an  upper  limit.  Accordingly,  we  place  a  high  premium  on  the 
continued  development  of  machinery  for  this  purpose. 

53.  If  it  is  necessary  to  complement  personal  income  tax  abatement,  as  appears 
likely,  we  are  attracted  by  the  possibility  of  instituting  provincial  sharing  of  federal 
consumption  tax  revenue.  Such  a  move  is  complicated  by  the  British  North 
America  Act,  which  in  restricting  the  provinces  to  direct  taxation,  precludes 
provincial  sharing  of  indirect  consumption  tax  revenue  by  the  abatement  technique. 
In  the  absence  of  an  appropriate  constitutional  revision,  the  alternative  is  for  the 
federal  government  to  pay  to  the  provinces  a  portion  of  its  revenue  from  the  general 
manufacturers'  sales  tax  and  other  excise  duties.  The  admitted  deficiency  of  this 
scheme  is  that  the  provinces  would  receive  revenue  from  tax  rates  they  had  not 
levied.  But  it  may  well  be  preferable  to  the  final  alternative — additional  abatement 
on  the  corporate  income  tax. 

54.  However  apportioned  among  income  and  consumption  taxes,  Ontario's 
need  for  additional  tax  room  from  the  federal  government  is  unambiguous.  We 
therefore  recommend  that: 

Ontario  negotiate  with  the  federal  government  for  substan-         8:3 
tial  tax  room  over  and  above  any  abatements  that  might  be 
granted  in  lieu  of  existing  shared-cost  programs. 


283 


Appendix  A 


ORGANIZATIONS  FROM  WHICH  SUBMISSIONS  WERE  RECEIVED 

Arthur  Andersen  &  Co.* 

Association  of  Assessing  Officers  of  Ontario,  The  Research  Committee* 

The  Association  of  Canadian  Distillers* 

The  Association  of  Mining  MunicipaUties  of  Northern  Ontario* 

The  Association  of  Ontario  Counties* 

Association  of  Ontario  Land  Economists* 

Association  of  Ontario  Mayors  and  Reeves* 

Automotive  Transport  Association  of  Ontario* 

The  Board  of  Education  for  the  City  of  Toronto 

The  Board  of  Education  for  the  Township  of  North  York 

The  Board  of  Trade  of  MetropoHtan  Toronto* 

Building  Owners'  and  Managers'  Association  of  Toronto 

Bureau  of  Municipal  Research* 

Caland  Ore  Company  Limited 

The  Calvin  Christian  School  Society  of  Toronto^ 

The  Canadian  Arthritis  and  Rheumatism  Society 

The  Canadian  Arthritis  and  Rheumatism  Society,  Ontario  Division 

Canadian  Automobile  Chamber  of  Commerce 

The  Canadian  Bankers'  Association 

Canadian  Bar  Association  (Ontario  Division),  Commercial  Law  Subsection* 

Canadian  Book  Publishers'  Council* 

Canadian  Booksellers  Association 

Canadian  Construction  Association  and  Affiliated  Ontario  Construction 

Associations* 
Canadian  General  Electric  Company  Limited 
Canadian  Institute  of  Steel  Construction 
The  Canadian  Life  Insurance  Officers  Association* 
The  Canadian  Manufacturers'  Association* 
Canadian  National  Railways* 
Canadian  Pacific  Railway  Company* 
The  Canadian  Rehabilitation  Council  for  the  Disabled 
Canadian  Underwriters'  Association 
Canadian  Wholesale  Council 
Canadian  Wine  Institute 
City  of  Niagara  Falls 
City  of  Sarnia 
City  of  Toronto 


♦Presented  brief  at  a  hearing  of  the  Committee. 

tPresented  at  a  public  hearing  with  three  others  as:  Ontario  Alliance  of  Christian  Schools. 

284 


Volume  1 


The  Committee  of  Presidents  of  Provincially  Assisted  Universities  and 

Colleges  of  Ontario* 
Communist  Party  of  Canada,  Ontario  Executive  Committee* 
The  Conservation  Council  of  Ontario* 

Consumers'  Association  of  Canada,  Ontario  Provincial  Association* 
Corporation  of  the  City  of  Fort  William 
The  Corporation  of  The  Townships  of  Medora  and  Wood 
The  County  of  Ontario* 
The  Equitable  Income  Tax  Foundation 
Gas  and  Petroleum  Association  of  Ontario 
Hamilton  Automobile  Club 
Immanuel  Christian  School  of  East  Torontot 
Imperial  Oil  Limited 

Imperial  Tobacco  Company  of  Canada  Limited 
The  Independent  Secondary  Schools  in  Ontario 
The  Institute  of  Chartered  Accountants  of  Ontario* 
The  Inter-Church  Committee  on  Legal  Affairs* 
The  Investment  Dealers'  Association  of  Canada* 
The  Life  Underwriters  Association  of  Canada 
M.  Loeb  Limited 

Motion  Picture  Theatres  Association  of  Ontario 
Municipal  Clerks  and  Finance  Officers  Association  of  Ontario 
The  National  Council  of  the  Baking  Industry* 
North  Western  Ontario  Municipal  Association 
Old  Yonge  Estates  Ratepayers  Association 
The  Ontario  Alliance  of  Christian  Schools* 
Ontario  Association  of  Architects 
Ontario  Bar  Association,  Taxation  Subsection* 
Ontario  Barbers  Association 
Ontario  Brewers'  Institute* 
Ontario  Carbonated  Beverage  Association* 
The  Ontario  Chamber  of  Commerce* 
Ontario  Credit  Union  League  Limited 
Ontario  Educational  Association 
Ontario  Federation  of  Agriculture* 
The  Ontario  Federation  of  Anglers  &  Hunters  Inc. 
Ontario  Hospital  Association* 

The  Ontario  Library  Association,  and  The  Ontario  Library  Trustees  Association 
Ontario  Medical  Association* 
Ontario  Mining  Association* 
Ontario  Motor  League 

Ontario  Municipal  Purchasing  Agents'  Association* 
Ontario  Professional  Foresters  Association 


*  Presented  brief  at  a  hearing  of  the  Committee. 

tPresented  at  a  public  hearing  with  three  others  as:  Ontario  Alliance  of  Christian  Schools. 

285 


Appendix  A 

Ontario  Property  Owners  Association,  and  Property  Owners  Association  of 

Metropolitan  Toronto* 
Ontario  Provincial  Council  of  Women* 
Ontario  Pulp  and  Paper  Companies 
Ontario  Retail  Lumber  Dealers  Association  Inc. 
Ontario  School  Trustees'  and  Ratepayers'  Association,  Inc.* 
The  Ontario  School  Trustees'  Council* 
Ontario  Separate  School  Trustees'  Association,  and  L'Association  des 

Commissions  des  Ecoles  Bilingues  d'Ontario* 
Ontario  Teachers  Federation* 
Ontario  Women's  Liberal  Association 
Petroleum  Association  of  Ontario* 
Public  Utilities  Commission  of  the  City  of  Kingston 
The  Retail  Council  of  Canada* 
Roman  Catholic  Bishops  of  Ontario* 
Scarborough  and  Associated  Farmers  Association* 
School  of  Economic  Science,  The  Alumni  Group* 
Timothy  Christian  School  Association  of  Torontot 
Toronto  District  Christian  High  School  Associationt 
Toronto  Parking  Operators  Association 
Toronto  Stock  Exchange 

Town  Planning  Institute  of  Canada,  Central  Ontario  Chapter* 
Trans-Canada  Pipe  Lines  Limited 

The  Trust  Companies  Association  of  Canada,  The  Ontario  Section* 
The  United  Church  of  Canada* 

United  Electrical,  Radio  and  Machine  Workers  of  America 
The  Urban  Development  Institute  (Ontario  Division)* 
Vaughan  Farmers  Association 
Windsor  Estate  Planning  Council 
York  County  Federation  of  Agriculture* 


*Presented  brief  at  a  hearing  of  the  Committee. 

tPresented  at  a  public  hearing  with  three  others  as:  Ontario  Alliance  of  Christian  Schools. 


286 


Appendix  B 


INDIVIDUALS  FROM  WHOM  SUBMISSIONS  WERE  RECEIVED 

Best,  Ralph  L.  Brantford 

Blackwell,  J.  M.  Scarborough 

Blanchard,  Thomas  R.  Toronto 

Bricker,  Harold  Hamilton 

Bristol,  Everett,  Q.C.  Toronto 

Bunt,  Lome  E.  Toronto 

Capon,  Frank  S.,  C.A.*  Montreal 

Clark,  Charles  R.  Angus 

Cookson,  T.  A.  Toronto 

David,  Thomas  Toronto 

Donovan,  William  A.*  Chatham 

Dorland,  Ray  O.  Chatham 

Edwards,  W.  A.  Toronto 

Fisher,  Charles  P.  Kitchener 

Homsey,  G.  La  Salle 

Kee,  Douglas  Toronto 

Keele,  Mrs.  Mary  J.  Kingston 

Kennedy,  Peter  J.  Brockville 

Kent,  Mayor  W.  A.  Newmarket 

Kernighan,  H.  S.,  P.Eng.*  Milton 

Laurie,  R.  M.  London 

LeLoup,  R.  H.*  Toronto 

Long,  Norman  W.  Toronto 

Lorenzen,  Francis,  C.A.  Windsor 

Lucas,  Miss  Mary  Welland 

Maclaren,  G.  F.,  Q.C.  Ottawa 

Mannell,  Laurie  S.*  Oakville 

Mcintosh,  James  Ottawa 

Mcintosh,  John  Toronto 

McKinney,  Norman  Toronto 

Menard,  Mrs.  Lena  Campbell  Hawkesbury 

Mortinez,  Mrs.  T.  Taylor  Toronto 

Pocock,  R.,  P.Eng.  Woodbridge 

Ralph,  Mrs.  WiUiam  Falconbridge 

Robert,  Miss  Germaine  Ottawa 

Schofield,  Frank  Dunnville 

Smith,  Marshall  Y.  London 

Smith,  P.  J.  Toronto 


''Presented  brief  to  a  hearing  of  the  Committee. 

287 


Appendix  B 

Smith,  William 

Scarborough 

Stronach,  Mayor  F.  Gordon 

London 

Templeton,  Gilbert 

Toronto 

Thili,  John 

Toronto 

Wardle,  Ernest 

Ottawa 

White,  Frank  A. 

London 

Wood,  W.  C. 

Guelph 

Woodward,  A.  J. 

Toronto 

♦Presented  brief  to  a  hearing  of  the  Committee. 


288 


Appendix  C 

STAFF  AND  CONSULTANTS 

Officials 

F.  Warren  Hurst,  F.C.A.       Executive  Director 


Secretary 
Editorial  Director 


Consumers  Gas  Co, 

Toronto 
Ontario  Treasury  Board, 

Toronto 
University  of  Toronto, 
Toronto 
Director  of  Economic       University  of  British 
Studies  Columbia,  Vancouver 

F.  Gerald  Townsend,  C.A.    Director  of  Tax  Thorne,  MulhoUand, 

Structure  Studies  Howson  &  McPherson, 

Toronto 


Hugh  R.  Hanson 
Prof.  J.  Stefan  Dupre 
Prof.  Robert  M.  Clark 


Research  Staff 
Anthony  G.  S.  Careless 
Dr.  Kenneth  Cheng 
Colin  C.  Dalingwater,  C.A. 
Robert  C.  Evans 
Lionel  D.  Feldman 
James  Forsyth,  C.A. 
Frank  G.  Felkai 
Vinay  A.  Gupta,  C.A. 
Mrs.  Ann  L  MacGregor 
William  Reynolds 
John  L.  Scadding 
John  G.  Sheldrick,  C.A. 
Mrs.  M.  Jacqueline  Taylor 
John  D.  Taylor,  C.A. 
C.  Robert  Tyson 
Lawrence  A.  Ward 
Henry  L.  E.  White 

Editorial  Associates 
Frederic  H.  Finnis 
Prof.  D.  G.  Hartle 
Prof.  J.  E.  Hodgetts 
Prof.  D.  C.  MacGregor 
Prof.  David  Nowlan 
Ronald  Robertson 


University  of  Toronto,  Toronto 

Department  of  Economics  &  Development,  Toronto 

Toronto 

Harvard  University,  Cambridge 

Toronto 

Treasury  Department,  Hamilton 

University  of  Toronto,  Toronto 

Treasury  Department,  Toronto 

Department  of  Municipal  Affairs,  Toronto 

Arthur  Andersen  &  Co.,  Toronto 

University  of  Chicago,  Chicago 

Toronto 

Toronto 

Toronto 

University  of  Toronto,  Toronto 

University  of  Toronto,  Toronto 

Osgoode  Hall,  Toronto 


Toronto 

University  of  Toronto,  Toronto 
University  of  Toronto,  Toronto 
University  of  Toronto,  Toronto 
University  of  Toronto,  Toronto 
Canadian  Tax  Foundation,  Toronto 


289 


Appendix  C 

Editorial  Assistants 
Mrs.  Millie  Goodman 
Robert  A.  Fenn 
Cash  Mahaffy 
Geoffrey  Matthews 

Co-ordinating  Editor 
Mrs.  Barbara  Urquhart 

Indexer 

Gerald  Brougham 


Canadian  Tax  Foundation,  Toronto 

University  of  Toronto,  Toronto 

Toronto 

University  of  Toronto,  Toronto 


Toronto 


Toronto 


Secretarial 

Miss  Rosalind  E.  Boyd 
Miss  M.  Josephine  Coulthard 
Miss  Ann  Kesnesky 
Mrs.  Wilma  M.  Snell 

Consultants  and  Research  Study  Authors 


Prof.  John  R.  Allan 
George  Bam 
Prof.  Clarence  L.  Barber 
W.  A.  Beckett  Associates 

Ltd. 
Brian  Bixley 
W.  D'Arcy  Blair,  Q.C. 
Prof.  Ronald  M.  Bums 


McMaster  University,  Hamilton 
Upper  Lakes  Shipping  Ltd.,  Toronto 
University  of  Manitoba,  Winnipeg 
Toronto 


University  of  Toronto,  Toronto 
Toronto 

Queen's  University,  Kingston 
William  A.  Bradshaw,  C.A.  Canadian  Institute  of  Chartered  Accountants, 

Toronto 
Department  of  Finance,  Ottawa 
Toronto 
Toronto 
Wahn,  Mayer,  Smith,  Creber,  Lyons,  Torrance 

and  Stevenson,  Toronto 
University  of  Toronto,  Toronto 
University  of  British  Columbia,  Vancouver 
University  of  Toronto,  Toronto 
Ottawa 


Douglas  H.  Clark 
Philip  T.  Clark,  F.C.A. 
James  Cole 
G.  Edward  Creber,  Q.C. 


Prof.  John  H.  Dales 
Lloyd  F.  Dctwillcr 
Prof.  Ian  Drummond 
A.  Kenneth  Eaton 

(deceased) 
Stanley  E.  Edwards,  Q.C, 


Arnold  Englander 
Ronald  J.  Farano 
J.  Eric  Ford,  C.A. 
Michael  D.  Goldrick 


Eraser,  Beatty,  Tucker,  Mcintosh  and  Stewart, 

Toronto 
Toronto 

Goodman,  Cooper,  Cohen  and  Farano,  Toronto 
Clarkson,  Gordon  &  Co.,  Toronto 
Bureau  of  Municipal  Research,  Toronto 


290 


Volume  1 


Wolfe  D.  Goodman 
Dr.  John  A.  G.  Grant 
Frank  J.  Hamill 
Prof.  C.  Lowell  Harriss 
Prof.  Dennis  C.  Hefferon 
Laratt  T.  Higgins 

John  M.  Hodgson 
E.  A.  Jarrett,  F.C.A. 
G.  H.  Johnson,  C.A. 
Prof.  Harry  G.  Johnson 
Prof.  James  A.  Johnson 
W.  J.  Johnston 
Prof.  Bora  Laskin 
William  H.  Merritt 
Prof.  J.  B.  Milner 
Prof.  A.  Milton  Moore 
John  Palmer,  C.A. 
Peat,  Marwick,  Mitchell 

&Co. 
J.  Harvey  Perry 
Joseph  Perry 
Henry  M.  Ploeger 

Prof.  Kenyon  E.  Poole 
B.  U.  Ratchford 
Robert  F.  Reid,  Q.C. 
Prof.  John  Sawyer 
Prof.  Anthony  Scott 
Dr.  Eric  C.  Sievwright 
James  I.  Stewart 
Prof.  Robert  W.  Thompson 
David.  Y.  Timbrell,  C.A. 
Dr.  Mabel  Walker 
Prof.  J.  C.  Weldon 
Prof.  Philip  H.  White 
Gerald  I.  M.  Young 


Goodman,  Cooper,  Cohen  and  Farano,  Toronto 

Wood,  Gundy  &  Co.,  Toronto 

Blake,  Cassels  and  Graydon,  Toronto 

Columbia  University,  New  York 

Osgoode  Hall,  Toronto 

Hydro-Electric  Power  Commission  of  Ontario, 

Toronto 
Blake,  Cassels  and  Graydon,  Toronto 
Glendinning,  Campbell,  Jarrett  &  Dever,  Toronto 
Thorne,  Mulholland,  Howson  &  McPherson,  Toronto 
University  of  Chicago,  Chicago 
McMaster  University,  Hamilton 
The  Municipal  Board  of  Manitoba,  Winnipeg 
University  of  Toronto,  Toronto 
Philips  Electronics  Industries  Ltd.,  Toronto 
University  of  Toronto,  Toronto 
University  of  British  Columbia,  Vancouver 
McDonald,  Currie  &  Co.,  Toronto 
Toronto 

Canadian  Bankers'  Association,  Toronto 
Northwestern  University,  Evanston 
Department  of  Economics  and  Development, 

Toronto 
Northwestern  University,  Evanston 
Federal  Reserve  Bank,  Richmond 
Day,  Wilson,  Campbell  &  Martin,  Toronto 
University  of  Toronto,  Toronto 
University  of  British  Columbia,  Vancouver 
Toronto 

Stewart,  Young  and  Mason,  Toronto 
McMaster  University,  Hamilton 
McDonald,  Currie  &  Co.,  Toronto 
Tax  Institute  of  America,  Princeton 
McGill  University,  Montreal 
University  of  British  Columbia,  Vancouver 
Stewart,  Young  and  Mason,  Toronto 


291 


Appendix  D 


STUDIES  TO  BE  PUBLISHED  BY  THE  COMMITTEE 

Study  A  uthor 

The  Incidence  of  Government  Revenues  and  Dr.  James  A.  Johnson 

Expenditures 

Intergovernmental  Finance  in  Ontario:  Dr.  J.  Stefan  Dupre 

A  Provincial-Local  Perspective 

The  Ontario  Business  Tax  William  H.  Merritt 

Ontario  Estates  in  1963-64:  A  Tabular  Analysis  of  Dr.  Kenneth  Cheng,  Dr. 

Personal  Wealth  held  in  Estates   out  of  which  John  A.  G.  Grant,  and 

Ontario  Succession  Duties  were  Paid  Henry  M.  Ploeger 

The  Retail  Sales  Tax:  An  Economic  Study  Dr.  Kenyon  E.  Poole 

Theory  of  Fiscal  Policy  as  Applied  to  a  Province  Dr.  Clarence  L.  Barber 


292 


Index 


Abbott,  D.  C,  on  transportation  tax,  39:  5 

Ability  to  pay: 

development  of  progressive  tax  system, 

1:  40 
and  the  law  of  diminishing  marginal 

utility,  1:  41-7 
as  principle  of  tax  equity,  1:  35-50 
see  also  under  specific  taxes 

Accessions  tax,  28:  12-17 
defined,  28:  12 

difficulties,  administrative,  28:  17 
difficulties  of  application,  28:  14-16 

Accounting  systems,  public: 
municipal,  9:  100-101 
national-accounts  approach,  3:  40;  24: 

14 
"ordinary"  and  "capital"  expenditure, 

3:39 
provincial,  24:  7-14 

Advertising    cost,    retail    sales    tax    on, 
29:  69-71 

Advisory  Committee  on  Child  Welfare, 
1964  report,  23:  90 

Aged,  homes  for  the,  21:  55-7 

Agreements  for  sale  and  purchase:  and 
succession  duties,  28:  104 

Agricultural  Rehabilitation  and  Develop- 
ment Act,  11:  191 

Agricultural  Societies  Act,  property  tax 
exemption,  12:  16 

Agriculture: 

labour  force,  reduced,  4:  8 
relative  decrease  in  net  value,  4:  8 

Agriculture,  Department  of: 

community  centre  grants,  21:  82 

loans,  36:  6 

revenue  from  sales,  37:  13 

Aitcheson,  J.  H.,  10:  6,  12n 

Alberta: 

administration  of  justice,  responsibility 

for,  9:91 
amusements  tax  —  none,  31:  22 
corporate  income  tax,  27:  2 
county    system    and    school    finance, 

20:77 


Alberta:  —  Continued 

and  the  death  tax  structure,  28:  68 

federal  hospital  operating  grants,  com- 
pared with  per-capita  income, 
38:37 

fire  insurance  tax,  31:  73 

forest  resources,  revenue  from: 
Crown  dues,  33:  12 
tenure  charges  (1964),  33:  10,   11 

home-owner  grants,  11:  83 

income  tax,  personal,  adoption  of, 
26:  3,  48 

interprovincial  movements  of  persons, 
26:  138,  139 

motor  vehicle  fuel,  tax  rate  on,  30:  7 

motor  vehicle  licensing  reciprocity  with 
Ontario,  30:  60 

motor  vehicle  registration  fees  (1964) 
T30:4 

municipal  revenue  from  permits  and  li- 
cences, 17:  7 

municipal  utilities,  revenue  from,  17:  50 

mineral  production: 
royalty  on,  32:  24 
value,  1966,  T32:  5 

mining  lands  taxes,  T32:  9;  32:  144, 
145 

mining  tax,  type  of,  32:  24 

poll  tax  abolished,  16:  5 

retail  sales  tax,  1936-37,  29:  12 

retail  sales  tax  —  none  today,  29:  18, 
99 

succession  duty,  adoption  of,  28: 48, 
50 

tobacco  tax  —  none,  31:  7 

wine  prices,  T35:  5 

see  also  Provinces 

Alcoholic  beverages,  revenue  from, 
35:  1-91 
background,  35:  3-11 
burden,  35:  64-8 

liquor  licence  fees,  35:  68 
spirits  and  beer,  35:  65-6 
wine,  mark-ups  and  taxes  on,  35:  67 
and  consumer  demand,  35:  75-85 
elasticity  and  revenue,  35:  84-5 
federal-provincial  policy  co-ordination 

needed,  35:  91 
fifth   most  important  revenue  source, 
35:  1 


Chapter  numbers  are  in  bold  face;  paragraph  numbers  in  light  face.    T= Table. 
Vol.  I,  1-8;  Vol.  II,  9-23;  Vol.  Ill,  24-40 


293 


Index 

Alcoholic  beverages  —  Continued 
general  considerations,  35:  63-91 
general  recommendations,  35:  86-91 
growth    and   sources   of   revenue,   35: 

9-11 
justification,  35:  69-74 
social  costs,  35:  70-72 
social    policy    based    on    consensus, 
1:  67,  68,  72;  35:  73-4 
Liquor    Licence    Board,    licences    and 

fees,  35:  42-54 
liquor  licences  and  "monopolistic  com- 
petition", 35:  48,  52 
liquor  regulation,  development  of,  35: 

3-8 
mechanics    of    sale    and    control,    35: 
12-27 
Liquor  Control  Board,  35:  13,  14-16 
Liquor  Licence  Board,  35:  21-7 
off-premises  consumption,  35:  13-19 
on-premises  consumption,  35:  20-27 
statutes  governing,  35:  12 
pricing  policies,  35:  6,  28-62 

fees  for  wineries,  breweries,  35:  37 
gallonage  tax  on  beer,  35:  39-41 
tax  on  Canadian  wine,  35:  38 
principal  sources,  35:  11 
projected    increase    (1968-69),    8:  34, 

36,  39 
reason     for    government's    traffic     in 

liquor,  35:  1,  88 
related  aspects  of  revenue  policy, 

35:  55-62 
taxes   and   fees   on  sale   of  Canadian 

wine  and  beer,  35:  36-41 
US    and    UK    studies    on    price    and 
income    elasticity    of    demand, 
35:77-81 
implications  for  Ontario,  35:  82-3 
see  also   Liquor  Control   Act,  Liquor 
Control    Board,    Liquor    Licence 
Act,  Liquor  Licence  Board 

Alcoholism: 

and  beer-drinking,  35:  90 
rates  of,  1939-61,  35:71-2 

Alcoholism  and  Drug  Addiction  Research 
Foundation,  35:  90;  38:  1 1 

Alcoholism  and  Drug  Addiction  Research 
Foundation  Act,  property  tax  ex- 
emption, 12:  16 

Allan,  James  N.,  and  introduction  of 
retail  sales  tax,  29:  17 

Allan,  John  R.,  on  the  income  tax  burden 
on  Canadian  shareholders,  27:  47n 

Amusements  tax:  see  Hospitals  tax 

Andrews,  J.  M.,  see  Johnson,  A.  W. 


Annual  Report  of  Municipal  Statistics: 
discrepancies   in  exemption   data,    12: 

21-2 
inadequacies    of    debt    reporting,    22: 

110-14 
weaknesses  of,  9:  97-103 

Annuities:    small,   exemption    from    suc- 
cession duties,  28:  130 

Art  galleries:  sales  tax  exemptions,  29:  78 

Arthritis  and  Rheumatism  Society,  38:  50 

Assessment,  provincial  taxes  —  general 

procedures,  25:  13-15 
government  should  publish  information 

memoranda,  25:  15 
limitation  of  assessment  period,  25:  13 
reason    for    tax    demands    should    be 

stated,  25:  14 

Assessment,     real     property,     11: 27-68, 
13:  1-169 
appeals:    see    Local    revenue    system, 

appeals 
assessed  value  and  taxable  assessment, 

11:  67-8 
Assessment  Branch  of  Department  of 

Municipal  Affairs,  10:  95 
bridges  and  tunnels  crossing  provincial 

boundaries,  13:  63-4 
capital  vs  rental  value,  11:  35-40 
cost  of  levying  and  collecting,  13:  5 
county  assessors,  10:  92-3 
changes,  late  nineteenth  century,  10:  30 
date  and  frequency  of  valuation, 

11:  49-52 
determining     actual     value,    statutory 

direction  for,  11:  31-3 
defining   value   for  property   tax   pur- 
poses, 11:  30 
equalization: 

county,  13:  139-43;  18:21-2 
provincial,  10:  81,  105;  11:  55-9;  13: 
90,  119,  137-47 
equalization  indexes,  13:  31 
equitable  assessments,  achievement  of, 

11:  29 
of  exempt  and  payments-in-lieu  prop- 
erties, lag  in,  10:  99 
fixed,  12:  153-66 
function,  13:93-115 

the  Assessment  Manual,  13:  108-15 
"assessment"  vs  "appraisal",  11:44; 

13:98-104 
estimating  value,  13:  105-7 
the  year's  work,  13:  93-7 
golf  courses,  10:  116;  12:  155-7 
and   grants   to   school   boards,   20:  12, 

13.  14 
Hydro-Electric  Power  Commission, 
13:69-71 


294 


Index 


Assessment,  real  property  —  Continued 
improving  standard  of,  10:91-5 
inequities  of,  13:  App. 
in  law  and  in  practice,  10:  78-81 
municipal  utilities,  13:  65-8 
1940  values,  10:  79,  81;  13:  10 
pipe  lines,  transmission,  13:  54-9 
present  vs  highest  and  best  use,  11:  41-3 
problems    stemming    from    legislation, 
13:  33-88 
assessment,  basis  of,  13:  40 
assessors,    appointing   and   licensing 

of,  13:  39 
statutory  sources,  13:  33-8,  App. 
uniformity,  steps  toward,   13:  41-5 
provincial  manual,  10:  95,  106;  13:  30 
provincial  statutes  other  than  The  As- 
sessment Act  with  a  bearing  on  the 
assessment  function,  13:  App. 
"rack  rent"  as  assessed  value,  10:  23 
railways,  13:  60-62 

reform,  alternative  paths  of,  13:  116-35 
assessment  at  present  value, 

13:  125-8 
local    vs    provincial    administration, 

13:  116-24 
reassessment,   needed  frequency  of, 
13:  129-35 

census  taker's  review,  13:  134 
reported  changes,  13:  134 
spot  checking,  13:  134 
three-year  inventory,  13:  134 
valuation    data,    processing   of, 
13:  134 
reform,  preparation  for,  13:  136-69 
cost  and  timing,  13:  165-8 
developing  a  professional  approach, 
13:  148-53 

licensing   of  all   municipal  asses- 
sors, 13:  152 

training  program,  13:  151 
equalization,  13:  137-47 

county   equalization,    13:  139-43 
large  assessment  units,  proposed, 
13:  146 

systems  of  equalization,  13:  138-9 
public   acceptance   of  actual   value, 
13:  154-64 
reform  in  progress,  13:  89-92 
requirements: 

comprehensive  coverage,  13:  2,  4 
equitability,  13:  3,  4 
separating   the    residential    assessment 

from  the  farm,  13:  85-8 
special-assessment  properties, 
10:  107-8,  13:46-84 
problems,  13:  72-84 


Assessment,  real  property  —  Continued 

state  of  assessing  in  Ontario,  13:  8-32 

Assessment  Branch  Survey,  13:  24-5 

assessing    practice,    shortcomings 

of,  13:  25 

discrimination    against    classes    of 

properties,  13:  13,  16 
farm  assessments,  13:  18-23 
inequalities,  causes  and  consequences 

of,   13:  29-32 
parallel  findings  in  the  rest  of  Can- 
ada, 13:  26-8 
under-assessment,   problem   of, 

13:  9-12,  App. 
variation  within  one  class  of  prop- 
erty, 13:  14-16 
statutory  valuation,  10:  7 
telephone    and    telegraph    companies, 

13:  47-9 
total   taxable,   unequalized   (1965)   12: 

1,  19 
transportation  companies,  13:  50-53 
under-assessment,     problem     of,     10: 
105-6,  11:  27-68  passim,  13:  9-12. 
App. 
exempt  properties,  12:  2 
utility  companies,  13:  50-53 
valuation  restored  to  assessor,  10:  12 
value     by     comparison     with     similar 

properties,  11:  34 
value  in  exchange,  11:  44-6 
valuing  land  and  structures  separately, 

11:47-8 
yield.  13:  6 

Assessment  Act,  10:  92;  13:  passim;  33:  1 
assessors,    appointment   and   licensing, 

13:  39 
assessment,  basis  of,  13:  40 
and  the  Beckett  Committee,  10:  89 
"business"  not  defined,  11:  138 
county  —  role  in  collections,   14:  68 
exemptions,  12:  12,  13,  105 
forested  land,  12:  149,  152 
places  of  worship,  12:  119,  120 
exemptions    from    business    tax,     12: 

169-72 
"farm"  not  defined,  11:  202 
function  of,  13:  34 
improved   basic   definitions    suggested, 

11:23-5 
instalment  payment  of  tax,  14:  37 
"land"  —  use  of  word,   11:  17-19 
and  levying  taxes  by  mining  munici- 
palities,  12:  175-6 
methods  of  enforcing  collection.  14:  59 
and  mining  profits  tax,  10:  71 


Chapter  numbers  are  in  bold  face;  paragraph  numbers  in  light  face.    T^ 
Vol.  1,  1-8;  Vol.  II,  9-23;  Vol.  Ill,  24-40 


:  Table. 


295 


Index 


Assessment  Act  —  Continued 

and  mining  properties,  12:  175-87;  32: 

53 
and  The  Mining  Tax  Act,  32:  18 
overdue  taxes,  mterest  on,  14:  54 
prepayment  of  taxes,  14:  48 
and  property  valuation,  10:  107-8 
Provmcial  Land  Tax  Act  and  Local 
Roads  Boards  Act,  assessment  pro- 
visions of,  transferring  to  Assess- 
ment Act,  13:  41-5 
special-assessment     properties,     11: 

165-74 
status  of  County  Judge,  18:  3 
tax  sales  procedure,  14:  79,  81,  82 

Assessment  Act  of  1793,  10:  3,  6,  7 

Assessment  Act  of  1803,  10:  7 
made  permanent,  1825,  10:  8 

Assessment  Act  of  1850,  10:  17-23 
amendments  to,  10:  18-22 

Assessment  Act  of  1853,  10:  23 

Assessment  Act  of  1866,  10:  25-6 

Assessment  Act  of  1904,  10:  53-60,  61 

exemptions,  26:  39-40,  43 

and  Maclennan  Commission,  10:  53-60 
passim 

and  municipal  personal  income  taxes, 
26:  38-41 

personal  employment  income  exemp- 
tions, 26:  40,  43 

steps  toward  compliance,  26:  41 

Association  of  Assessing  Officers,  10:  94 

Association  of  Ontario  Counties,  and 
local  government  reform,  23:  17 

Atlantic  provinces: 
poll  tax,  use  of,  16:  3 

Atlantic  Smoke  Shops  Ltd.  v.  Conlon 
and  A  ttorney-General  for  Canada, 
30:  29n 

Attorney  General,  Department  of,  fee 
revenue,  37:  4,  T37:  1 

Australia,  capital  gains,  26:  194 

Baldwin  Act  (1849),  10:  15,  33 

Bank  of  Canada,  monetary  policies  and 
supply  of  capital,  26:  17 

Banks:  corporate  taxes,  27:  8,  9,  127,  133 

Barber,  Clarence  L.,  3:  lOn,  29n  34n 
on    unbalancing    of    the    government 
budget,  3:  5 

Basic  shelter  exemption: 

cost  of  establishing,  11:1 14-17 
50  per  cent  ceiling,  11:  103 
fiscal  effects,  1966,  8:  6,  T8:  2 


Basic  shelter  exemption:  —  Continued 
and  landlords  holding  long-term  leases, 

11:  113 
level  of  property  taxation,  impact  on, 

11:  102 
mechanics,  11:  108-11 
proposed,  11:  100-119 
recreational  properties,  11:  126,  128-30 
and  regressiveness  of  the  property  tax, 

11:  106 
and    residential   taxpayers,   effects  on, 

11:  104-5 
shared-occupancy  accommodation,  11: 

101,  112 

Basic  Shelter  Exemption  Grant,  8:  13,  24, 
25,  40,  43;  11:  117-18;  21:96 
will  mitigate  regressiveness  of  property 
tax,  8:  10,  25 

Beach  Protection  Act,  32:  1 

Beaver  Valley  Developments  Limited  v 
Township  of  North  York,  15:  75 

Beckett  Committee:  see  Select  Committee 
on  The  Municipal  Act  and  Related 
Acts 

Beer,  draft:  gallonage  tax,  35:  39-41 
sales  tax  exemption,  29:  74 

Bell  Telephone  Company,  17:  36 

Beneficiary  under  succession  duty: 

effects  of  proposed  rate  schedule,  28: 

168 
obligation  to  pay  duties,  28:  171,  173 
proposed  classes,  28:  146 
and  rates  of  tax,  28:  152-4 
in  Succession  Duty  Act,  28:  56,   129 

Benefits  received: 

earmarking  and  funding,  1:  31-2 

and  fees,  1:  27 

as  principle  of  tax  equity,  1:  26-34 

where  inappropriate,  1:  29 

see  also  under  specific  taxes 

Bentham,  Jeremy,  28:  24 

Bird,  Frederick  L.,  13:  15 

Blind  Persons'  Allowance,  federal  abate- 
ment for,  26:  114,  115 

Blind  Persons'  Allowance  Act,  38:  73 
and  OMSIP  premiums,  38:  16 

Board  of  Review  (proposed):  25:  30 
costs  of  hearing  before,  25:  36 

Boards  and  commissions: 

finances  not  reported  in  Public  Ac- 
counts, 24:  8 

revenue  responsibility  should  be  under 
Department  of  Provincial  Reve- 
nue, 25:  8 


296 


BoUens,  John  C,  on  the  fragmentation  of 
governmental  activities,  23:  34n 

Bollinger,  Lynn  L.,  see  Butters,  J.  Keith 

Bondett,  Harold,  formula  for  mining  pay- 
ments, 12:  228-9 

Books,  and  sales  tax  exemptions,  29:  79 

Boy    Scouts    Association,    property    tax 
exemption,  12:  13,  105 

Bradshaw,  Thomas:  on  municipal  credit 
worthiness,  22:  119 

Brandon,    Manitoba,    personal    property 
tax  replaced  by  business  tax,  10: 
-    38 

Break,  G.  F.,  on  income  taxes  and  the 
incentives  to  work,  26:  12n 

Breweries,  fees  for,  35:  37 

Brewers'  own  retail  stores: 

percentage  of  total  sales  of  alcoholic 

beverages,  35:  29 
sale  and  control  of  alcoholic  beverages: 

off -premises  consumption,  35:  13, 

18 

Brewers'  Warehousing  Company  Ltd: 

creation  of,  35:  5 

percentage  of  total  sales  of  alcoholic 
beverages,  35:  29 

ratio  of  operating  expenses  to  sales, 
35:61 

sale  and  control,  off-premises  consump- 
tion, 35:  13,  17 

British  Columbia: 

administration  of  justice,  responsibility 

for,  9:91 
alcoholism  rates,  1939-61,  35:  71 
amusements  tax  —  none,  31:22 
commercial  vehicles,  municipal  licens- 
ing of,  30:  80 
corporate  income  tax,  27:  2 
and  death  tax  structure,  28:  68 
federal  hospital  operating  grants,  com- 
pared    with     per-capita     income, 
38:  37 
forest  resources,  revenue  from,  33:  35 
Crown  dues,  33:  12 
logging  tax,  33:  40 
rental  based  on  area,  33:  28 
rental  based  on  stumpage,  33:  26 
tenure   charges,   33:  10-11 
home-owner  grants,  11:  83 
income  taxes,  27:  1 1 
interprovincial  movements  of  persons, 

26:  138,  139 
meals  tax,  29:  54 


Index 

British  Columbia:  —  Continued 

mineral  production  value,  1966,  T32:  5 
mining  acreage  tax,  T32:  9,  32:  144 
mining  profits  tax,  rates  of,  32:  124 
mining  tax: 

base,    32:  25-31    passim 
rates  and  basic  exemption,  32:  32,  33 
type  of,  32:  24 
motor  vehicle  fuel  tax  rate,  30:  7 
motor  vehicle  licensing  reciprocity  with 

Ontario,  30:  60 
motor  vehicle  registration  fees  (1964), 

T30:4 
municipal  revenue  derived  from 
permits  and  licences,   17:  7 
personal  income  tax  (1876), 

26:  2,  3,  48 
personal  property  tax,  10:  38 
poll  tax  abolished,  16:  5 
property  tax  collections,  percentage 

collected,  14:  24 
real  property,  assessment  of,  11:  32 
retail  sales  tax,  29:  15 

production  machinery,  29:  67 
succession  duties,  28:  40 
assessment  of,  28:  224 
compared  with  Ontario  and  Quebec, 

28:  155 
dispositions,  three-year  period  prior 

to  death,  28:  107 
increased  tax  credit,  1964,  26:  75 
introduction  of,  28:  48,  49 
re-entry  into  (1963),  26:  73 
uniform  statutes,  28:  226 
tobacco  tax.  T31:  1 
water  power  rentals,  34:  16,  17 
see  also  Provinces 

British  North  America  Act,  2:  11,  18,  43 
federal  abatement  of  consumption 

taxes,  8:  53 
interpretations  by  Judicial  Committee 

2:  17 
limitation   of  provinces  to   direct 

taxation,  25:  9,  26:  1 
and  municipal-provincial  relations, 

2:69 
and  property  tax  exemption,  12:  6 
and  provincial  taxing  powers,  26:  36 
separate  schools,  2:  114 
succession  duty: 

vs  estate  tax,  28:  44 
tax  base  for,  28:  61 
taxation  of  government  entities,  2:  61 
tax-exempt  status  of  provincial 

properties  and  HEPC,  12:  30 


Chapter  numbers  are  in  bold  face;  paragraph  numbers  in  light  face.    T= Table. 
Vol.  L  1-8;  Vol.  n,  9-23;  Vol.  IH,  24-40 


297 


Index 


Buchanan,  James  M.: 

on  federalism  and  fiscal  equity 

2:  48n,  49n 
the  pubUc  finances,  27:  73 

Budget  Statement  (provincial),  24:  5 

Buffalo  and  Fort  Erie  Public  Bridge 

Authority,  fixed  taxation,  13:  63-4 

Burlington  Skyway,  30:  74,  79 

Business,  definition  of,  11:  138-40 

Business,  family:  and  succession  duties, 
28:  189-96 

Business  income: 

allocation  of  between  provinces, 
26:  102-10 
complications  of  varying  tax  rates, 

26:  145-53 
part-time  resident  of  Canada, 
26:  108 
loss  carry-over,  -back,  26:  180 

Business  taxes:  11:  131-207 
alternatives,  11:  141-6 

charges   for   municipal   services, 

11:  144 
non-property  taxes,  11:  143 
turnover  tax,  11:  145-6 
appraisals  of,  10:  88 
assessment    and    taxation,    10:110-11; 

11:  131-64 
farm  properties,  11:  178-207 
importance  to  municipalities,  6:  22 
improvement  of,  11:  147-57 

flat-rate  business  tax,  effects  of, 
11:  152-7 
and   interprovincial  competition, 

11:  151 
mining  properties,  11:  175-7 
ordinary  realty  tax,  11:  133-7 
proposed,  11:  158-64 

effects  on  current  leases,  11:  160-63 
occupant  tax,  11:  159 

problem   of   tax   delinquency, 
11: 164 

realty  tax  on  owner,  11:  159 
proposed  by  Maclennan  Commission, 

10:  40,  42-3 
and  school  costs,  11:  136 
transportation  and  communications 

properties,  11:  165-74 
types  of,  11:  131-2 
variable  rate,  6:  2,  24-5;  11:  132 
weakness,  11:  149-51 

Butters,  J.  Keith,  Lawrence  E.  Thompson 
and  Lynn  L.  Bollinger, 
Effects  of  Taxation:   Investment  hy 
Individuals,   26:  19n 


Cairns  Construction  Ltd.;  v.  Government      || 
of  Saskatchewan,  30:  29n  1 

California: 

hotel  and  motel  rooms  tax,  19:  5,  7n 
retail  sales  tax  audit,  29:  103 

Canada  Assistance  Plan,  21:  43,  45 
and  Children's  Aid  Societies,  21:  53 

Canada  Pension  Plan:  funds  used  for 
school   borrowing,   20:  47; 
22:  136-7 

Canada  Student  Loan  Plan,  36:  7 

Canadian  Good  Roads  Association,  on 
road  classification,  21:  23 

Canadian  National  Exhibition  Associa- 
tion: exempt  from  Hospitals  Tax 
Act,  31:  15 

Canadian  National  Railways,  payment  of 
full  local  taxes,  12:  80,  88 

CPR  V.  Sudbury,  13:  80n 

Canadian  Red  Cross  Society,  38:  50 
property  tax  exemption,  12:  165 

Cancer  Act,  property  tax  exemption, 
12:  16 

Capital,  flow  of,  effect  of  corporate  in- 
come tax  on,  27:  35-7 

Capital  gains,  26:  187-201;  27:  102;  28:  2 
conclusions,  26:  201 
economic  effects  of  tax,  26:  199-200 
equity  vs.  certainty,  26:  197 
lack  of  tax  permits  escape  from  taxes 

by  reinvestment,  27:  72 
minimum  conditions  for  tax,  26:  198 
practices  in  other  countries,  26:  190-95 
problems  of  distinguishing  from  tax- 
able income,  26:  188-9,   196 
question  of  equity,  26:  189,  195-9 

Capital  levies,  special,  15:  4-57 

apportioning  the  cost  of  projects, 
15:  36-44,  54-7 
exemptions,  15:  41-2,  53 
municipal  share,  15:  37-8 
owner's  share,  15:  39-40 
capital  works  financed  by,  15:  7-9 
definition,  15:  4 

initiating  works  financed  by,  15:  10-35 
Drainage    Act    and    Tile    Drainage 

Act,  15:  4,  27-29 
Local  Improvement  Act, 

15:4,  11-19,  34 
Municipal  Act,  15:  4,  20-25,  34 
municipal  council,  15:  34-5,  52 
Ontario  Water  Resources  Commis- 
sion Act,  15:  4,  26 
Police  Act,  15:  4,  33 
Public  Utilities  Act,  15:  4,  32 
Telephone  Act,  15:  4,  30-31 


298 


Capital  levies,  special  —  Continued 
rationalizing,  15:  45-57 
revenue  from,  15:  5-6 

see  also  Developers,  capital  works 
financed  by 

Capreol,  Frederick  Chase,  39:  28 

Cemeteries,  property  tax  treatment,  12: 
129-32 

Centennial  Centre  of  Science  and  Tech- 
nology Act,  property  tax  exemp- 
tion, 17:  16 

Central  Canada   Exhibition  Association, 
exempt   from   Hospitals  Tax, 
31:  15 

Central  Mortgage  and  Housing  Corpora- 
tion, 14:  40;  22:  42-5 
municipal    borrowing   through,    inade- 
quately reported,  22:  113 

Charitable,  community  service  and  other 
non-profit  organizations:  property 
tax  exemption,  1:  67,  69,  72;  12: 
133-43 

Children's  Aid  Societies,  21:  2,  39 
property  tax  exemption,  12:  13 
and  public  welfare,  23:  86 
special  status,  12:  142 
and  welfare  grants,  21:  53-4 

Children's  Institutions  Act,  21:  53 

Children's  Mental  Hospitals  Act,  property 
tax  exemption,  12:  16 

Churches:  see  Places  of  worship 

Citizens  Research  Institute:  and  the 

growth  and  nature  of  subdivision 
agreements,  15:  62n,  63-8 

City  Engineers'  Association,  and  the 

growth  and  nature  of  subdivision 
agreements,  15:  63-8 

Civil  Service,  Department  of,  no  inciden- 
tal revenues,  37:  2 

Clark,  Robert  M.,  Development  of  the 
Personal  Income  Tax,  26:  43n 

Coins:  sales  tax  exemption,  29:  81 

Colleges  of  Applied  Arts  and  Technology: 

see  under  Education 
Commission  on  Municipal  Institutions 
(1888),  10:  33 

on  personal  property  tax,  10:  37 

Commission  on  Municipal  Taxation 

(1893),  and  personal  property  tax, 
10:  37 


Index 

Commission  on  Railway  Taxation,  1904, 
10:51-2 
and  special-franchise  properties,  10:  52 

Commission  on  Taxation,  1893,  10:  34 
and  exempt  properties,  10:  102 

Commission  on  Workmen's  Compensation 
Act' 
1950,  38:  58n 
1966,  38:  58n 

Common  Schools  Act  of  1816,  20:  6,  11 

Common  Schools  Act  of  1850,  10:  16 

Communications  properties;  see  Trans- 
portation and  communications 
properties 

Community  Centres  Act,  property  tax 
exemption,  12:  15 

Community  Enrichment  Grant,  proposed, 
21:  85-9 

Community  of  property;  and  succession 
duties,  28:  81-2 

Community  Psychiatric  Hospitals  Act, 
property  tax  exemption,  12:  16 

Community  services,  grants  for,  21:  81-9 

Conditional  grants:  see  under  Federal- 
provincial  shared-cost  programs; 
Grants 

Conservation  Authorities  Act,  property 
tax  exemption,  12:  15 

Conservation  grants,  21:  65-6 

Consumption  expenditure,  as  index  of 
tax-paying  capacity,  1:  36-9 

Corporate  financing,  efi'ects  of  corporate 
income  tax,  27:  59-61 

Corporate  income  tax,  27:  24-113 
allocation  of  income,  problems  of, 

27:  80-83 
collection  agreement: 

advantages  of,  26:  122;  27:  85-9 

assurance  of  additional  tax  from 

reassessments,  27:  89 

bad-debt   losses,    elimination   of, 

27:88 

economy  and  efficiency  of  admin- 
istration, 27:  87 

reduction  in  cost  of  compliance, 

27:  86 

uniformity,  27:  85 
disadvantages.  27:  90-96 

misallocation   of   taxable    income 

among  provinces,  27:  92 

rate  limits,  possibility  of,  27:  91 


Chapter  numbers  are  in  bold  face;  paragraph  numbers  in  light  face.    T=Table. 
Vol.  I,  1-8;  Vol.  II,  9-23;  Vol.  Ill,  24-40 


299 


Index 


Corporate  income  tax, 
collection  agreement: 

disadvantages  —  Continued 

tax  base,  loss  of  autonomy  over, 
27:  94-6 

weaker  bargaining  position,  27:  93 
recommendation,  27:  97 
description,  27:  24-8 
different    provincial    rates,    and    geo- 
graphic distribution  of  investment, 
27:  67 
economic    consequences    of    increase, 

8:4-7 
economic  effects,  27:  50-67 

Canadian  exporters,  competitiveness 

of,  27:  62-7 
corporate  financing,  27:  59-61 
investment,  27:51-8 

absence     of    capital     gains     tax, 
27:52 

adverse  effects,  27:  56 
effect    of    rates    higher    than    federal 

abatement,  26:  155 
effect  on  flow  of  capital,  27:  35-7 
equity,  27:  41-9,  69-72,  74 
ability  to  pay,  27:  41-2 
"double    taxation    of   corporate    in- 
come", 27:  43ff 
and  personal   income   taxes,   27:  43 
retained   portions  of   the   corporate 
profits,  27:  46ff 
federal    corporate    taxes,    sharing    of 

special,  27:  105 
first  imposed  by  provinces,  27:  1 1 
incidence,  problem  of,  27:  29-40 
long-run  shifting,  30:  34-7 
separate  entity  vs.  a  type  of  partner- 
ship, 27:  30 
short-run  shifting,  27:  31-3 
statistical  evidence  on  the  shifting  of, 
27:  38-40 
inferior  source  of  added  revenue,  8:  18 
justification  for,  27:  68-84 
levied  by  Province,  10:  75 
municipal,  10:  75,  76,  77;  19:  15 
need  for  uniformity,  27:  78-9 
1952  tax  rental  agreement,  26:  57 
1962  changes  in,  27:  13 
non-resident  withholding  taxes,  27:  106 
and  personal  income  tax,  problems, 

26:  186 
projected  increases,  8:  33,  34,  36,  37, 

39 
reintroduced,  1957,  26:  61 
reliance  on,  27:  74-7 
shifting,    and    economic   effects,    27: 

51-67  passim 
shifting,    and    problem    of   equity, 
27:  42-9 


Corporate  income  tax  —  Continued 

should  be  integrated  with  personal  in- 
come tax,  27:  49,  74,  101 

tax  base,  federal-provincial  consulta- 
tion on,  27:  98-102 

yield,  27:  68 

see  also  Corporations  tax 

Corporate    tax    adjustment    grant,    and 
the  elementary  school  boards, 
20:  28-30 

Corporations  Information  Act,  27:  124 

Corporations  tax,  27:  1-144 
admmistration,  27:  16-22 

cost  of  operating  the  Branch,  27:  19 
notices  of  income  tax  reassessment, 

27:21 
numbers  of  corporations,   1964, 

27:  18 
tax  roll,  maintaining,  27:  16-17 
administration  and  appeals,  recommen- 
dation, 27:  136-44 
appeals,  27:  23 

categories  of  corporations,  27:  8 
corporations,    first   taxed    as    separate 

entities,  10:  30 
deduction  for  mining  tax,  32:  137 
exemptions    from  insurance   premium 

taxes,  31:  74 
federal  tax  on  corporate  distribution, 
effect  on  provincial  personal  in- 
come tax  base,  8:  50 
federal    tax    on    utilities,    transfer    to 

provinces  of,  27:  103-4 
first  imposed,  10:  51 
history,  27:  6-15 

no  allocation  to  provinces,  27:  8 
and  insurance  taxes,  27:  72 
in  lieu  of  taxes  on  corporate  distribu- 
tions— provinces   should  share  in 
yield,  26:  129,  132-3 
and  local  income  taxes,  19:  15 
and  the  logging  tax,  26:  160;  33:  43 
paid-up   capital    and   place-of-business 

taxes,  27:  11,  4-25 
as  percentage  of  P.D.P.,  6:  49 
problem  of  finding  base  of  taxation, 

27:  8 
projected  revenue  from,  T6:  7 
and  provincial  government  enterprises, 

36:21 
reintroduced,  1957,  26:  61 
revenue,   1961-66,  27:  5 
revenue    1965-66,    and    administrative 

body,  T25:  1 
special  taxes,  27:  126-35 

chartered  banks,  27:  126,  133 
conclusions,  27:  133 
express  companies,  27:  130,  133 
insurance  companies,  27:  132,  133 
railway  corporations,  27:  128,  133 


300 


Corporations  tax, 

special  taxes  —  Continued 

sleeping,    parlour    and    dining    car 

companies,  27:  131,  133 
summary,  27:  134-5 
telegraph  companies,  27:  129,  133 
tax  rental  agreements,   26:  57; 

27:  13-14 
various  Ontario   taxes  introduced, 

27:  12,  T27:  2 
see  also  Corporate  income  tax 

Corporations  Tax  Act,  1957,  27:  14-15 

appeal  procedure,  25:  27 

conflict  with  federal  Income  Tax  Act, 
-     27:  App. 

definition  of  "permanent  establish- 
ment", and  the  retail  sales  tax, 
29: 114 

elimination  of  conflict  between  federal 
and  provincial  statutes,  27:  107-13 

and  Mining  Tax  Act,  32:  134 

"permanent  establishment",  26:  103 

refund,  conditions  for,  25:  19 

Crawford,    K.    G.,    Canadian   Municipal 
Government,  9:  93n,  12:  29 

Creighton,    Donald,    on   liquor   controls, 
35:4 

Crown  Timber  Act,  33:  1,  2,  4-39 
historical  background,  33:  5-6 
present  revenue  structure,  33:  7-9 
and  property  tax  exemption,  12:  14 
types  of  charges; 

Crown  dues,  33:  8-9 

severance,  33:  8 

tenure,  33:  8 
types  of  cutting  licences,  33:  7-9 

district  cutting,  33:  7-8 

order-in-council,  33:  7-8 

sales,  33:  7-8 

salvage,  33:  7-8 

Dalton,   Hugh,   on  multiple   tax  system, 
1:  55-6 

Death  taxes,  28:  18-23 
characteristics,  28:  24-46 
defined,  28:  19 

economic  consequences  of,  28:  34-9 
effect  of  on  total   accumulation   of 

capital  goods,  28:  38 
impact  on  savings,  28:  35-7 
private  businesses,  effect  on  owners, 

28:  39 
private  wealth,  reduction  in  size, 
28:  34 
federal    government    should    withdraw 
from  field,  28:  221,  225-6 


Index 

Death  taxes  —  Continued 

federal-provincial  sharing  of,  28;  223-6 
importance    of    uniform    statutes, 

28:  226 
incidence,  28:  24-33 
distribution  by  size  of  estate,  28:  32-3 
shifts   in   liquidity  of  assets,   28:  27-8 
justification,  28:  20-22 
and    1962   federal-provincial  fiscal 

arrangements,  26:  64 
1963  federal-provincial  conference  on, 

26:  73,  75 
succession  duties  vs.  estate  taxes, 

28:  40-46 
responsibility  of  payment,  28:  173-6 
see  also  Estate  tax;  Succession  duties 

Debentures,  municipal,  22:  32-3 

Debt:  see  Municipal  debt;  Provincial 
debt 

Debt,  government:  projection,  1966-75, 
6:  1-128 

Debt  guarantees:  of  public  enterprises,  by 
the  Province,  36:  22-3 

Democracy,  constitutional: 

basic  purpose  the  common  good,  1:  5-6 
individual  rights  and  duties,  1:7-11 
and  society,  1:  12-15 
and  taxation,  1:  3-20 
two  elements  of,  1:4 

Denmark: 

capital  gains,  26:  193 
wealth  tax,  annual,  28:  9 

Dependant's  allowance,  and  succession 
duty,  28:  131 

Dependant's  allowance  and  reductions: 
not  used  in  proposed  succession 
duty  rate  structure,  28:  169 

Dependant's  reduction,  28:  132 

Developers,  capital  financing  by, 

15:  58-92 
and  Department  of  Municipal  Affairs, 

15:71-9 
future  policy,  15:  86-92 
role  in  municipal  expansion,  15:  80-85 
subdivision  agreements,  15:  60-70 

Disabled  Persons'  Allowance,  federal 
abatement  for,  26:  114,    115 

Disabled  Persons'  Allowance  Act,  38:  73 
and  OMSIP  premiums,  38:  16 

Dispositions:  and  death  duties,  28:  105-10 

District  Councils  Act  of  1841,  10:  10 


Chapter  numbers  are  in  bold  face:  paragraph  numbers  in  light  face.    T^Table, 
Vol.  I,  1-8;  Vol.  II.  9-23;  Vol.  Ill,  24-40 


301 


Index 

Domicile,  law  of,  and  succession  duties, 
28:  63-4,  206,  209 

Dominion     Unemployment     Relief    Act 
(1930),  21:42 

Drainage  Act,  capital   levies   (special) — 
initiating  works  financed  by, 
15:  4,  27-9 

Due,  John: 

provincial  sales  tax,  29:  66n 
on  retail  sales  tax  audit,  29:  103 

Dupre,  J.  Stefan,  23:  88n 

Intergovernmental  Finance  in  Ontario, 

9:92n;  20:  lln;  21:  3n,   103n 
Ontario  grant  breakdown,  21:  7n 

Durham  Report,  10:  11,  14 

Dymond,  M.  B.,  and  OMSIP  and  OHCIP 

integration,  38:  77n 


Eckstein,  Otto,  on  modern  fiscal  theory, 
3:6 

Economic  objectives: 

conflicts  among,  3:  14-17 

and  lenders  and  borrowers,  3:  15 
importance  of  diagnosis  to  attainment 
of,  3:41-42 

Economic  policy: 

instruments  of,  3:  11-13 

main  objectives,  1:  16-17 

means  of  achieving,  1:  18-20 

and  neutrality  in  taxation,  1:  57,  59 

"Economic  rent",  32:  40;  33:  25;  34:  6 
definition,  9:  39n 

Economic  stability,  and  employment 
level,  3:  15,  16 

Edmonton: 

business  tax,  variable  rates,  11:  151 
personal    property    tax,    replaced    by 
business  tax,  10:  38 

Education: 

College    of    Applied   Arts    and  Tech- 
nology; 
capital  costs,  projection,  6:  88 
operating  costs,  projection,  6:  85-7 
finance  and  local  government  structure, 
internal    organization,    23:  158-65 
"foundation"  schemes,  2:  129 
legislation  to  change  school  areas  and 

districts,  23:  9-10 
needs  of  the  labour  force,  4:12 
post-secondary,  6:  60-72 

cost  to  Province,  T6:  9,  T6:  22 
cost  implications  of  possible  changes 

in  system  of,  6:  91-7 
distribution  of  students.  6:  66-70 
enrolment  projection,  6:  63-72 


Education: 

post-secondary  —  Continued 
projected  expenditure,  6:  57-97 

superannuation,  6:  58-9 

teachers'    colleges    operating    and 

capital  costs,  6:  83-4 

university  capital  costs,  6:  79-82 

university    debt    service    charges, 

6:  89-90 

university  operating  costs — projec- 
tion, 6:  73-8 
provincial  capital  grants  to  universities, 

6:  82 
in  rural  municipalities,  and  recreational 

properties,  11:  126-7 
secondary    schooling    and   the   county 

regions,  23:  91-7 
teachers'  colleges: 

effect  if  degree  required,  6:  95-6 
universities,  sources  of  revenue,  6:  75-8 

Education,  Department  of: 

assessment    administration    in    school 

areas,  13:  35,  38 
fee  revenue,  37:  4,  T37:  1 
grants  for  public  libraries,  21:  81 
non-profit  camps  grant,  21:  6 
and  property  tax  exemptions  of  insti- 
tutions  of  higher  learning, 
12:  110,  112 
recreational    programs,    grants    for, 
21:  82 

Emergency  Gold  Mining  Assistance  Act, 
32:  13,  14,  27,45,  67-71 

Emergency   Measures   Organizations, 
grants  to,  21:  90 

Employment: 

fluctuations  in,  and  economic  stability, 

3:  15,  16 
projection,  6:  8 
wage  and  salary  earners,  and  welfare 

measures,  4:  10 
working  definition  of  fuU  employment. 

3:  16 

Energy  and  Resources  Management,  De- 
partment   of,    municipal    park 
grants,  21:  82 

Equalization  payments,  2:  23-31 
basis  of,  2:  24-7 

place  in  provincial-municipal  relations. 
2:76 

Equity: 

and  capital  gains  tax,  26:  189,  195-8 
corporate  income  tax,  27:  41-9.  69-72. 

74 
dependent  on   distribution  of  burdens 

and  benefits,  8:  10 
and  equalization  policy.  2:  47-8 


302 


Equity:  —  Continued 

importance  of  knowledge  of  net  fiscal 

incidence,  5:  49 
prime    characteristic    of    tax    system, 

1:20 
the  principle  of  ability  to  pay,  1:  35-50 
principle  of  benefits  received,  1:  26-34 
earmarking  and  funding,  1:  31-2 
when  inappropriate,  1:  29 
principle  of  equal  treatment  of  equals, 
1:21-5 
justification  of  taxes,  1:  25 
protection,  1:  23-5 
relates  solely  to  individual  or  family, 

1:  50 
unequal  treatment  of  unequals,  1:  25 

Established  Programs  (Interim  Arrange- 
ments) Act,  26:  74 
"opting-out"    formula,    provincial    tax 
credits,  26:  114-15 

Estate  Tax  Act: 

assets  held  in  safety  deposit  box, 
28: 182 

dispositions  made  in  three-year  period 
prior  to  death,  28:  107 

and  foreign  ownership,  28:  208 

and  life  insurance,  28:  101 

payments  from  employers  of  the  de- 
ceased, 28:  98 

and  quick  succession,  28:  116 

taxing  powers  of  the  federal  govern- 
ment, 28:  67 

Estate  taxes: 

administration  of,  28:  41 

assessment,  28:  200 

correlation  with  income  tax,  28:  225 

deductions,    and    exemptions,    28:  133 

gift  tax  credit,  28:  213 

method  of  payment,  28:  174 

Ontario's   share,   projection   of,   6:  50, 

T6:7 
and  the   1962   federal-provincial  fiscal 

arrangements,  26:  71 
vs.  succession  duties,  28:  40-46 
and  the  BNA  Act,  28:  44 
differences,  28:40-41 
tax  rate,  compared  with  U.S.  and  U.K., 

28:  156 
rebate  to  provinces,  28:  49 
see  also   Death    tax;   Succession   duty 
Excise  taxes:  disadvantage,  1:  57 

Executor: 

payment  of  estate  taxes,  28:  174-5 
power  of  encroachment,  28:  201 
power  of  sale  to  pay  succession  duties, 
28:  176 


Index 

Exemptions,   property   taxes,    11: 26; 
12:  1-235 
as  alternative  to  grants,  12:  7,  8 
basic  shelter  exemption,  11:  100-119 
from  business  occupancy  tax,  12:  167- 
74 
farms,  12:  171 
private  clubs,  12:  170 
free  employee  parking,  12:  174 
rooming  houses,  12:  169 
and  shopping  centre  parking  areas, 

12:  168 
subordinate  lodges  and  friendly  soci- 
eties, 12:  172-3 
classification,  12:  21 
compulsory  exemptions,  12:  29 
educational,    religious,    charitable    ex- 
emptions, 1:  67,  69,  72;  12:  27-8 
federal  Crown  corporations  and  agen- 
cies, 12:  80 
federal  properties,  12:  74-88 

properties  excluded  from  grants-in- 

lieu,  12:  79,  82 
proposed  treatment  of,  12:  82-7 
appeal  procedures,  12:  86-7 
grants-in-lieu,  for  foreign  govern- 
ment properties,  12:  83 
Indian  lands,  12:  84 
school  grants,  26:  85 
recommendations  concerning,  12:88 
fixed  assessments,  12:  153-66 

the  golf  course  principle,  12:  155-7 
by  private  Act,  12:  158-66 
grants,    advantages    over    exemptions, 

12:  135-6 
historic  sites  and  monuments,  12:  55-8 
for  home  improvements,  11:  89-94 
Hydro  properties,  12:  35-41 
legislation   granting  exemptions, 

12:  12-17 
list  of  statutory  exemptions,   12:  App. 
local    government    properties,    12:  89- 
103 
inter-municipal  taxing,  12:  92-103 
holding    self-taxation    to    minimum, 

12:92-103 
municipal  utilities,  12:91 
mining  properties,  and  provincial  pay- 
ments   to    mining    municipalities, 
12:  175-235 
non-government  properties,  12:  104-52 
assessment    of    universities,    private 

schools  and  hospitals,  12:  118 
cemeteries,  12:  129-32 
charitable,    community    service    and 
other  non-profit  organizations, 
12:  133-43 


Chapter  numbers  are  in  bold  face;  paragraph  numbers  in  light  face.    T= Table. 
Vol.  I,  1-8;  Vol.  II.  9-23;  Vol.  Ill,  24-40 


303 


Index 


Exemptions,  property  taxes, 
non-government  properties  — 
Continued 

institutions   of   higher   learning, 

12:  108-12 
land  tor  forestry  purposes,  12:  144- 

52 
places  of  worship  and  other  religious 

property,  12:  119-28 
private  schools,  12:  113-14,  118 
public  hospitals,  12:  115-17 
payments-in-iieu,  shortfall  in,  12:  20 
percentages,    by    municipal    classifica- 
tion, 12:  25-6 
percentages,    by    type    of    exemption, 

12:24 
pros  and  cons,  12:  5-11 
provincial  and  Hydro  properties,  pro- 
posed treatment,  12:  35,  42-67 
assessment  of  property,  12:  43 
forested  lands,   12:  50 
highways,  12:  51 
land  betterment  works,  12:  52-8 
local  improvement  levies,  12:  48 
properties  providing  certain  services 

for  themselves,  12:  61-4 
provincial  parks,  12:  65-7 
public  housing,  12:  71 
remote  or  underdeveloped  lands, 

12:  59,  60 
school    boards,    allocation    of    pay- 
ments, 12:  44-7 
windfall  revenue,  12:  68-70 
provincial  properties,  12:  30-72 

Crown  and  Crown  agency  properties, 

12:31-4 
properties  excluded  from  taxation  or 

grants-in-lieu,  12:  34 
recommendations  concerning, 
12:  72-3 
relation  to  total  assessments,  12:  18-29 
significance,  12:  18-29 
total,  1965,  12:  1,  19 
treatment  of  municipal  utilities,  12:  22 
types  of  property  exempted,  12:  3 

Expenditure,  government: 
allocation  of,  1961,  T5:  3 
assumptions    regarding    allocation    of 

benefits,  5:  App. 
benefits    as     percentage    of    adjusted 

broad  income,  T5:  7 
factors  in  increase,  6:  4 
by  family  money-income  class,  T5:  4 
on    goods   and    services,    distinguished 

from  transfer  payments,  5:  19 
methods   of  estimating  benefits  from, 

5:  18-26 
"progressive"  and  "regressive"  benefit 

rates  defined,  5:  30 
projection,  1966-75,  6:  1-128 


Expenditure   and   revenue,   growing   gap 
between,  40:  1 

Expenditure,   gross   and   net,    distinction 
between,  4:  23 

Expenses,  business:  should  be  tax  deduc- 
tible, 27:  99 

Export  credits  v^.  corporate  (direct)  taxes 
— economic  effects,  27:  64 

Exports,  corporate  income  taxes,  effects 
on,  27:  62-7 

Express  companies:  corporate  taxes,  27: 
8,  9,  130,  133 

Fair   value,   determination   of   for   retail 
sales  tax  purposes,  29:  110 

Family  and  Social  Services,  Department 
of: 
grants  from,  21:  4 
low-rental  housing,  21:  78,  80 

Farm,  definition  of,  11:  202-7 
Farm  properties: 

assessment  of,  13:  18-23 

assessment  and  taxation  issues,  11: 

178-89 
effect  of  contracts,   or  quotas,    13: 

22-3 
on  farm  use,  11:  41 
separating   residence   from   working 

farm,  13:  85-8 
taxation  of,  11:   178-207 

assessment  and  taxation  issues,  11: 

178-89 
and  changing  character  of  farming, 

11:  195-8 
incidence,  11:  191-4 
local  services  to  farms,  11:  190 
proposed,  11:  199-201 
safeguarding  position  of  farm  lands 

under  realty  tax  system,   11:  186 
and  urban  encroachment,  11:  182-3, 

185,  186,  189 

Farmers: 

fuel  tax  exemption,  30:  22-7  passim 
retail  sales  tax  exemption,  29:  68 

Federal  government: 

corporate  income  tax,  27:  2 
corporate    taxes,    special,    sharing    of, 

27:  105 
and  counter-cyclical  fiscal  policy,  3:  8 
expenditure  (benefit)  rates,  by  income 

classes,  5:  34-5,  37 
expenditures  (benefits),  net,  gained  by 

residents  of  Ontario,  5:  42-3 
fiscal  incidence,  net,  pattern,  5:  46 
grants-in-lieu,    allocation    to    school 

boards,  12:  77 


304 


Federal  government:  — Continued 

has  greatest  elTect  on  income  distribu- 
tion, 26:  33 
hospital  grants,  38:  68-71 
construction  grants,  38:  26 

objections  to,  38:  28,  29 
operating  grants,  38:  35-42 

defects,  38:  37-9 
income    tax,    personal,    partial    with- 
drawal from,  26:  6 
income  taxes,  personal  and  corporate, 

introduction  of,  26:  4 
insurance  premiums  tax,  31:  73 
main  source  of  progressiveness  in  tax 

rates,  5:  46,  48 
rrionetary  policy,   sole  prerogative  of, 

3:  13 
and  municipal  borrowing,   22:  139-41 
non-resident  withholding  taxes,  27:  106 
opting-out  formula,  26:  63 
payments  in  lieu  of  local  taxes,  10:  85, 

99,  100,  12:  45 
provincial  income  taxes,  abatement  for, 

26:  111-18 
public    health,    research    and    training 

grants,  38:  45-9 
race  tracks  tax,  31:  41 
should    vacate    succession    duty    field, 

8:  50,  28:  221,  225-6 
as  source  of  funds  for  health  services, 

38:  20 
tax  abatements:  see  under  Taxation 
tax  rate  by  income  classes,  5:  30,  32-3 
taxing  powers,  unrestricted,  28:  67 
tobacco  tax,  increase  (1951-53),  31:  6 
university  support,  6:  75,  76 
utilities,  transfer  to  provinces  of  federal 

tax  on,  27:  103-4 
vocational  education  grants,  20:  67-71 
and  Wartime  Tax  Agreements,  26:  52 
exemptions:     see    under    Exemptions, 

property  tax 

Federalism: 

basic  principles  of  fiscal  arrangements, 

2:5-10 
Committee's  philosophy  of,  2:  2-10 
co-operation,  2:  8-9,  15,  32-40 
economic  mobility,  2:  6,  15,  22 
equalization    of    provinces,    2: 7,     15, 

23-31,  45-51 
expenditure  responsibilities,  division  of, 

2:  11-15 
fiscal  implications,  2:  5-66 
grants,  role  of,  2:  41-59 
the  nature  of,  2:  2-3 
need  for  flexibility,  2:  18-19 


Index 

Federalism:  — Continued 

provincial  and  federal  autonomy,  2:  5, 

14-15,  20-23 
revenue    powers,    the    division    of,    2: 

16-31 

Federal-provincial  conferences: 
1963,  26:  73 

1964 — Tax  Structure  Committee  estab- 
lished, 26:  76 

Federal-Provincial    Fiscal    Arrangements 
Act,  1961,  26:64 

Federal-provincial   shared-cost   programs 

abatements  in  lieu  of,  8:  51 

Canada  Assistance  Plan,  21:  43,  45,  53 

conservation  grants,  21:  65 

contracting  out,  2:  57-8;  26:  74 

criticism  of,  2:  54 

federal  contribution  to  Ontario's  health 
program,  T38:  23 

health  programs,  38:  20,  45-49 

federal    withdrawal    from   recom- 
mended, 38:  48 

hospital  construction,  38:  26-9 

hospital  insurance,  2:  53;  38:   10,   14, 
20,  34-43 
federal   withdrawal    from   recom- 
mended, 38:  42 

municipal  winter  works,  21:  90 

need  for  review,  2:  55 

old  age  assistance,  21:  38 

old  age  pensions,  21:  38 

philosophy  of,  2:  52-59 

redevelopment  and  housing,  21:  76 

Trans-Canada  Highway,  2:  53 

unemployment  assistance,  2:  53;  21:  42 

Federal-provincial  tax  arrangements,  2: 
18,  36-8 
consultation    on    corporate    base,    27: 

98-102 
federal   abatements  to   Province,   8: 

50-54 
and    municipal   corporation    income 

taxes,  10:  76 
mutual  taxation,  2:  60-66 
tax  collection  agreements,  26:  78-91 
administration  of  provincial  Act  by 

federal  government,  26:  79-81 
application   of   tax   collections,   26: 

87-8 
basis  and  rate  of  tax,  26:  85 
for  corporate  income  tax: 
advantages,  27:  85-9 
disadvantages,  27:  90-96 
recommendation,  27:  97 


Chapter  numbers  are  in  bold  face;  paragraph  numbers  in  light  face.    T=Table. 
Vol.  I,  1-8;  Vol.  II,  9-23;  Vol.  Ill,  24-40 


305 


Index 


Federal-provincial  tax  arrangements, 
tax  collection  agreements  — 
Continued 

defects,  26:  125-36 

notice  of  intention  to  change  pro- 
vincial rate,  26:  134-5 
provinces  should  share  in  yield  of 

more  taxes,  26:  129-33 
disputes   and  differences,  26:  91 
Ontario-Canada,  1936,  26:  51 
payments  to  Ontario,  26:  89-90 
powers    of    Minister    of    National 

Revenue,  26:  127 
provincial   tax,   changes  in  rate  of, 

26:  86 
reasons  for  continuing,  26:  123-4 
uniformity  of  legislation,  26:  82-4 
tax  rental  agreements,  26:  53-7 
drawbacks  of,  26:  54 
1947,  4:48;  27:  13,  14 
1952,  4:48;  27:  13,  14 
Ontario  in,  26:  56-7 
1957,  27:  13,  14 
"tax  room"  for  the  provinces,  26:  6 
tax-sharing  arrangements,  26:  58-63 
and  death  taxes,  26:  64,  66,  71,  73, 

75,  223-6;  28:  49 
drawbacks,  26:  120 
1957,  provisions  of,  26:  59 
1962,  26:  64-77 
personal    and    corporate    income 
taxes,  provincial  legislation  of, 
26:  68-70,  72 
opting-out  formula,  26:  63,  74 
provision  for  non-agreeing  provinces 
(1957),   26:  60 
Wartime  Tax  Agreements,  26:51,  52; 
27:  13 

Fees:   cost-recovery  principle,   17:  19-22, 
28-30;    35:  37,    48,    52,    54;    37: 
8,  22 
where  preferable  to  taxes,  1:  27 

Feldman,  Lionel  D.,  9:  92n 

Ferguson,  Howard,  21:  41 

Financial    Report   (provincial,   abridged), 
24:5 

Fines  and  forfeitures,  provincial  depart- 
mental revenue  from,  37:  19-20 

Finland,  capital  gains,  26:  193 

Finnis,    Frederic   H.,   on   Real   Property 
Assessment   in   Canada,    13:  117n 
Fire  Marshals  Act: 

abolition  of  tax  advocated,  31:  84 
and  insurance  premiums,  31:  72 
no  provision  for  appeal,  25:  27 
revenue  must  equal   expenses,  31:  72, 

76 
revenue,    1965-66,    and    administrative 
body,  T25:  1 


"Fiscal  drag",  defined,  3:  18 

Fiscal  effects  of  the   Recommendations, 
8:  1-54 

Fiscal  incidence,  net:  concept  of,  5:  38-44 

Fiscal  policy: 

"built-in"  flexibility,  3:  19 
changing  concepts  of,  3:  2-10 

fallacy  of  the   balanced   budget,  3: 
2-3,  6 
counter-cyclical,  3:  7-8 

combating  recessions,  3:  37-8 
provincial,  8:  20 

feasibility  of,  3:  29-42 
and  municipal  budgets,  3:  54-7 
scope  for,  40:  11-13 
need  for  federal-provincial  co-ordina- 
tion, 40:  14 
need  for  public  education,  3:  38 
"discretionary",  the  need  for,  3:  18-20 

"full-employment"  surplus,  3:  18 
and  economic  objectives,  3:  3-9 
factors  governing  borrowing,  3:  39 
as  instrument  of  economic  policy,  3: 

11-12 
not  to  be  regarded  as  "panacea",  3:  4 
provincial,  and  public  borrowing,  Com- 
mittee's philosophy  of,  3:  1-57 
trend  toward  decentralization,  3:  24-5 

Fish    and    wildlife,    revenue    from,    34: 

25-32 

Fishermen:    retail   sales   tax   exemptions, 
29:  68 

Foreign   governments,   and   property   tax 
exemption,  12:  83 

Foreign  tax  credit: 

and  corporate  income  tax,  27:  26 
and  Ontario  Income  Tax  Act,  1961-62, 
26:  163-5 

Forest-fire-fighting  costs,  grants  for,  21: 
90 

Forest  resources,  revenue  from,  33:  1-46 
alternative  revenue  methods,  33:  21-9 
profits  tax,  33:  22-5 
rental    based    on    annual    allowable 

cut,  33:  29 
rental  based  on  area,  33:  28 
rental  based  on  inventory,  33:  27 
rental  based  on  stumpage,  33:  26 
costs  of  stumpage  system,  33:  19,  20 
Crown  charges,  revised  system  of: 
proposed    tenure    and    severance 

charges,  33:  32-9 
shifting  and  incidence,  33:  30-31 
Crown  Timber  Act,  33:  4-39 


306 


Forest  resources,  revenue  from 
—  Continued 

and  forest  management,  33:  16-17 
and  high-grading,  33:  14 
and    holding    of    excessive    tracts    of 

timber,  33:  18,  20,  33 
Logging  Tax  Act,  33:  40-45 
and  Ontario  Income  Tax  Act,  1961-62 
— logging    tax    deduction,    26: 
159-62 
shifting  and  incidence,  33:  30-31,  32 
stumpage,  defects  of  system,  33:  13-20 
tenure  and  severance  charges  in  other 

provinces,  33:  10-12 
and  wasteful  logging  practices,  33:  15 
yield,  33:  2 
Forestry  Act,  33:  1 
Fort  William:  telephone  system,   15:  31; 

17:  36 
France: 

capital  gains,  26:  193 

exports  and  indirect  taxes,  27:  63 

lottery,  39:  26-7 

value-added  tax,  29:  7 

Fuel  taxes,  30:  5-30 

agency-collected,  25:  10 
constitutionality,  30:  28-30 
exemption  and  refunds,  30:  12,  22-7 
rates  and  administration,  30:  7-15 
refunds,  1964-65,  30:  25 
sales  tax  on  fuels,  30:  16-21 
vs.  weight-distance  taxes,  30:  108-9 
see  also  Gasoline  tax;   Motor  vehicle 
revenue 

Funeral  expenses:  as  deduction  for  suc- 
cession duty  purposes,  28:  122 

Garages:  licences,  30:  57-8 

Garden  City  Skyway,  30:  74,  79 

Gas  companies:  corporate  taxes,  2:  8,  28 

Gasoline:  and  retail  sales  tax,  29:  81;  30: 

16-21 
Gasoline    and    diesel    fuel    taxes,    8:  14, 
16-17,  18 
projected    increases    (1968-69),    8:  33, 
34,  36 
Gasoline  tax: 

agency-collected,  25:  10 

government  enterprises  liable  for,  36: 

20 
projected  revenue  from,  6:51,  T6:  7 
revenue,    1965-66,   and   administrative 

body,  T25:  1 
and  rising  highway  expenditure,  6:  98, 

99 
as  source  of  provincial  revenue,  4:  47 


Index 

Gasoline  Tax  Act: 

collection  and  control,  30:  13,  15 
definition  of  gasoline,  30:  1 1 
exemptions  and  refunds,  30:  23,  25 
no  provision  for  appeal,  25:  27 

General  Agreement  on  Tariffs  and  Trade 
(GATT),  27:  62 

General  Mining  Act,  32:  2 

General  Public  Health  Grant,  38:  47 

General  Welfare  Assistance  Act  of  1961, 

21:43 
George,  Henry,  10:  61 
Gibson,  T.  W.,  32:  fnl,  37 

on  the  concept  of  relating  tax  to  min- 
ing profits,  32:  3 

Gift  tax,  28:  11,  210-22 

credit  for  succession  duty,  28:  151 
and  dispositions,  28:  107,  109 
exemption  too  high,  28:  216 
proposed  for  Ontario,  28:  215-22 
exemption,  28:  217 
rates   and   computation  of  tax,   28: 

218 
responsibility  for  payment,   28:  220 
provinces  barred  from  imposing  during 

term  of  fiscal  agreement,  26:  85 
provinces   should   share   in  yield,    26: 
129,  131 
Girl    Guides    Association;    property    tax 

exemption,  12:  13,  105 
Golf    course,    fixed    assessment    of,    10: 
116;  12:  155-7 

Goodall,  B.,  see  Lean,  W. 

Goode,    Richard,   on   individual    income 

tax,  1:  45,  46 
Government  enterprises,   provincial,   36: 
1-23 

debt  guarantees,  36:  22-3 

lending  corporations,  36:  6-9 

major  enterprises,  36:  4-9 

need  for  review,  36:  10-19 

periodic  examinations  of  operations  a 
necessity,  36:  11-12 

providing  service  at  cost.  36:  2,  5 

reasons  for  entering,  36:  3 

should    be    subject    to    income    taxes. 
36:21 

taxation  of,  36:  20-21 

see    also    Municipalities:    revenue- 
earning  enterprises 

Government  finance:  expenditure  and 
revenue   patterns,   provincial   and 
local.  4:  22-55 
explanation  of  figures  used,  4:  22-3 


Chapter  numbers  are  in  bold  face;  paragraph  numbers  in  light  face.    T=^ Table. 
Vol.  L  1-8;  Vol.  n,  9-23;  Vol.  Ill,  24-40 


307 


Index 

Government    revenue    and    expenditure, 
incidence  of,  5:  1-49 

adjusted  broad  income,  defined,  5:  29 

allocating  benefits  of  general  expendi- 
ture, 5:  23-4 

allocation  of  benefits  of  major  expendi- 
ture programs,  5:  App. 

concept  of  '"economic  family",  5:  6 

difficulty  of  measuring  welfare,  5:  3 

eflective  benefit  rates,  5:  34-7 

eflfective  tax  rates,  5:  30-33 

general  conclusions,  5:  47-9 

importance  of  determining,  5:  2 

by  income  class,  5:  4-5 

method  of  estimating  benefits  from 
expenditure,  5:  18-26 

method  of  estimating  tax  incidence, 
5:9-17 

money  income,  defined,  5:  7 

money-income  classes,  burdens  and 
benefits  by,  5:  27-8 

net  fiscal  incidence  among  Ontario  resi- 
dents, the  pattern  of,  5:  45-6 

net   fiscal   incidence,    the    concept   of, 
5:  38-44 
defined,  5:  38-9 
interpreting,  5:  41-4 
limitations,  5:  40 

revenue  by  source,  1961,  T5:  1 

shifting  and  incidence  of  major  revenue 
sources,   5:  App. 
see  also  under  specific  taxes 

specific  and  general  governmental  ex- 
penditure differentiated,  5:  22 

taxes,  forward-shifted,  percentage 
borne  by  Ontario  residents,  5:  14 

taxes,  shifting  to  non-residents,  5:  11, 
13-15 

transfer  payments  and  expenditures  on 
goods  and  services,  distinguished, 
5:  19 

Governments: 

advantages  of  having  both  provincial 

and  local,  9:  15 
advantage  of  multi-level,  1:  15 
"borrowing  capacity",  3:  35 
changing  role  of,  4:  15-21 
economic  objectives,  major,  1:  16-17 

means  of  achieving,  1:  18-19 
increasing  complexities  of,  4:  16-18 
intergovernmental    fiscal    relationships, 

2:  1-131 
need  for  co-ordination,  3:  23-8 
need  for  increased  financial  capacity  to 

meet  increased  demands,  4:  54 
pressure  of  increased  population,  4:  7 
projection  of  expenditure,  revenue,  debt 

— projection    distinguished    from 

forecast,  6:  6-7 
taxation,  mutual,  2:  60-66 


Graham,  John  F.,  on  fiscal  adjustment  in 
a  federal  country,  2:  48n,  49n 

Grand  River  Conservation  Act,  property 
tax  exemption,   12:  16 

Grants: 

equalization  grants,  2:  45-5 1 
revenue  deficiency  grants,  2:  43-4 
the  role  of,  2:41-59,  91-9 
stimulation    grants    (shared-cost    pro- 
grams), 2:  52-9 

"contracting  out",  2:  57-8 

criticism  of,  2:  54 

types  of  standards,  2:  53 
types  of,  2:42,  91 

Grants,  federal: 

for  hospital  construction,  38:  26,  28 
inadequately  presented  in  Public  Ac- 
counts, 24:  11 
in  lieu  of  local  taxes,  6:  27 
National  Health  Grants,  38:  45ff 
for  universities,  26:  63 

Grants,  municipal: 

for  hospital  construction,  38:  27 

Grants,  provincial,  to  local  governments, 

4:30,  53;  6:33,  37-40,   112;  10: 

12;  21:  1-108 

administration    of   grant   policies,   21: 

103-8 

co-ordinating    grant    programs,    21: 

103-6 
provincial  grants  and  fiscal  policy, 
21:  107-8 
Basic  Shelter  Exemption  Grant,  8:  10, 
13,  24,  25,  40,  43;  21:96 
proposed,  11:  117-18 
for  benefit  of  residential  taxpayers,  11: 

78-80 
capital  grants,  22:  38 
changes    recommended — fiscal    effects, 

T8:  1,  T8:2;  8:23 
Community    Enrichment    Grant,    pro- 
posed, 21:  85-9 
conservation  grants,  21:  65-6 
environmental  grants,  21:  62-89 

equalization,  2:  93-5 
and  fiscal  policy,  21:  107-8 
health  grants,  26:  68-74 

for  health  units,  21:  69-74;  23:  85 
for  hospital  construction,  38:  26,  30-33 
jail  construction  and  operation,  9:  90 
miscellaneous  grants,  21:  90-93 
administration  of  justice,  21:  91 
certain    fur-bearing   animals,   21: 93 
police  and  firemen,  21:  92 
Municipal   Unconditional  Grants 
Act,  21:94-5 
number    of    grant    programs,    impos- 
sibility of  accurate  count,  21:  4-7 


308 


Grants,  provincial,  to  local  governments 
—  Continued 

for  public  health,  research  and  train- 
ing, 38:  49-56 
recreational   and   community   services, 
21:  81-9 
public  libraries,  21:  83 
redevelopment  and  housing,  21:  75-80 
for  relief  of  property  taxpayer,  10:  83-7 
revenue  deficiency,  2:  92 
road  grants,  21:  4,  9-35 

cities  and  separated  towns,  21:  15 

county  roads,  21:  12 

development  and  present  structure, 

21:9-17 
development  roads,  21:  32-5 
differential  grant  treatment,  21:  21-2 
equalization,  21:  12,  13,  27-9 
ministerial  discretion,  21:  30-35 
and  municipal  status,  21:  20-22 
need  for,  21:  18 
other  programs,  21:  16-17 
provincial  highways,  21:  10 
rationalizing  of,  21:  18-26 
should  be   geared  to   user   benefits, 

21:  19-20,  23-6 
suburban  roads,  21:  11 
summary    of   the    principal    road 

grants,  21:  17 
town  and  village  roads,  21:  14 
township  roads,  21:  13 
role   in  provincial-school  board  rela- 
tions, 2:91-9,  124-30 
rural  grants,  21:  67 
scheduling  through   the  year,   22:  63, 

65,  67 
school  grants,  2:  124-30,  20:  10-21 
capital,  8:  21 
increased: 

fiscal  effect,  8:  23-4 
and  projected  provincial  expendi- 
ture, 8:  31 
projected  increase  in,  8:  40-42,  43 

staging  of,  8:  42,  43 
proposed  increase  in,  20:  83 
revisions   recommended  —  fiscal  ef- 
fects, 8:  11-13 
for  secondary  schooling,  limitations 
of,  23:  94 
stimulation,  2:  96-9 
types  of,  21:  1 

unconditional  grants,  21:  94-102 
a  new  unconditional  grant  for  muni- 
cipalities, 21:  97-102 
to  universities  (capital),  6:  82 
welfare  grants,  21:  36-61 

Children's  Aid  Societies  and  related 
child  welfare  services,  21:  53-4 


Index 

Grants,  provincial,  to  local  governments, 
wellare  grants  —  Continued 
day  nurseries,  21:  61 
general  weltare  assistance,  21:  45-52 
historical  background,  21:  36-43 
homemakers'    and    nurses'    services, 

21:60 
homes  for  the  aged,  21:  55-7 
indigent  hospitalization,  21:  59 
local  administration,  problem  of,  21: 

47-52 
mothers'  allowances,  21:  37,  43 
old  age  pension,  21:  38 
present  status  and  existing  problems, 

21:44-61 
unemployment  relief,  21:  40-43 

Grauer,  A.  E.,  on  public  assistance  and 
social  insurance,  21:41n 

Grey  County,  pre-election  budgeting,  14: 
5,  6-9 

Gross  National  Product: 

and  full-employment  conditions,  3:  17, 
18 

provincial-municipal  finance,  percent- 
age of,  3:  21 

and  the  rate  of  tax,  26:  154 

Gundy,  C.  L.,  Medical  Research  in 
Canada,  38:  49n 

Hamilton,  City  of: 

capital  items  financed  from  revenue, 
22:  100 

poll  tax,  recommendation  for  abandon- 
ment, 16:  16-17 

Hanson,  Eric  J.: 

on  Alberta  county  educational  system, 

23:  162 
on  the  public  finance  aspects  of  health 

services  in  Canada,  39:  9,  37 

Harvard  Law  School,  Taxation  in  the 
Federal  Republic  of  Germany, 
39:  6n 

Health,  Department  of: 

Medical   Services    Insurance   Division, 

38:  16 
revenue  sources,  37:  4,  13;  T37:  1 
and  size  of  health  units,  21:  73-4 

Health  Facilities  Development  fund,  pro- 
posed, 38:  29,  47 

Health  grants,  from  province  to  munici- 
palities, 21:  68-74 

Health  Grants  Program,  federal  tax  abate- 
ment for,  26:  114,  115 


Chapter  numbers  are  in  bold  face;  paragraph  numbers  in  light  face.    T=Table. 
Vol.  I.  1-8;  Vol.  II,  9-23;  Vol.  III.  24-40 


309 


Index 


Health  services;  see  Hospital  and  Medical 
care,  financing  ot 

Health  Sciences  Research  Council,  38:  47 

Highway  Improvement  Act,  11:  66 
development  roads,  21:  32 
and  subdivision  agreements,  15:  83 
township  road  grants,  21:  13 

Highway  Traffic  Act,  administration   of 
permits  and  licences,  30:  34 

Highways  and  roads: 

cost    allocation,    "earnings-credit" 

method,  30:  92-3 
costs,  and  motor  vehicle  revenues,  30: 

82-96 
projected  expeditures,  6:  98-100 
toll  facilities,  30:  74-9 

and  road-building  decisions,  30:  77-9 

Highways,  Department  of:  revenues  from 
sales,  37:  13;  T37:  1 
see   also   Grants,  provincial,    to    local 
governments:  road  grants 

Hobbes,  Thomas,  36 
Home-owner  grants,  11:  83-6 
Hospital  and  medical  care,  financing  of, 
38:  1-81 
allocation  of  money  to  components  of 
health  program,  formulas  for,  38: 
24-56 
care  of  the  aged — problem  of  pension 

payments,  38:  52-3 
complicated  by  sharing  of  costs,  38:  4-5 
complicated  by  tradition  of  voluntary 

support,  38:  2,  3 
complicated  by  variety  of  components, 

38:6 
expenditure  projections,   6:  101-6 
Ontario  Hospital  Services  Commis- 
sion, 6:  102-3,  105 
Ontario  Hospitals,   operation  and 

maintenance  of,  6:  104-5 
Ontario  Medical  Services  Insurance 
Plan,  6:  106 
government  sponsorship  and  subsidiza- 
tion, stages  of,  38:  14-16 
health  services,  major  components  of, 

38:7-16 
hospital  construction,  38:  26-33 
federal  grants,  38:  26,  28-9 
provincial  grants,  38:  26,  30-33 
rehabilitation,  38:  26,  33 
TB  sanatoria,  38:  26,  33 
unmanageable  debt,  38:  26,  33 
range  of  costs  per  bed,  38:  30 
renovating  and  altering,  shared  costs 
for,  38:  32 
hospital  operating  costs,  38:  34-44 
hospitals,  functions  of,  38:  8-11 
hospitals,  types  of,  38:  10 


Hospital  and  medical  care,  financing  of 
—  Continued 
importance    of    public    knowledge    of 

costs,  38:  80-81 
indigents,  care  of,  38:  54-5 
insurance    plans,    underlying    social 

philosophy  of,  38:  64,  67,  71 
local  health  units,  co-ordination  of — 
and  regional  government,  38:  56 
municipal  expenditures,  projection,  6: 

35 
OMSIP  and  OHCIP: 
differences,  38:  78-9 
integration  of,  38:  76-81 
prominent  features  of,  38:  3-6 
public  health  agencies,  38:  12 
public   health,   research   and   training, 
38:  45-56 
federal  grants,  38:  45-9 
provincial  grants,  38:  49-56 
revenue  sources,  38:  17-23 

considerations    affecting    choice   of, 

38:63-81 
federal  government,  38:  20,  23 
local  governments,  38:  22,  23 
major  insurance  plans,  38:  19,  23 
the  Province,  38:  21,  23 
voluntary  contributions,  38:  18,  23 
subsidized    insurance    for    low-income 

people,  38:  55 
Workmen's  Compensation,  38:  57-62 

Hospital  Insurance  and  Diagnostic  Ser- 
vices Act  (1957),  2:  53;  38:  14, 
28,  34 

Hospital  insurance  program,  federal 
abatement  for,  26:  114,  115 

Hospital  Services  Commission  Act,  38:  7 

Hospitals: 

property    tax    exemption,    12:  115-17, 

118 
and  sales  tax  exemptions,  29:  74,  75, 
78 

Hospitals  tax,  31:  14-32 
agency-collected,  25:  10 
collection  of,  31:  18 
comparison  with  other  provinces,  31: 

22 
conclusion,  31:  32 
description,  31:  14-18 
discriminatory,  31:  30-31 
incidence,  31:  23-8 
justification,  31:  29-31 
and  motion  picture  industry,  31:  24-5 
payable  on  expenditure  in  a  place  of 

entertainment,  31:  17 
revenue,    1965-66,   and   administrative 

body,  T25:  1 
taxes  on  meals  and  beverages,  29:  59 
yield,  31:  19-21 


310 


Hospitals  Tax  Act,  19:  2;  31:  32 

no  provision  for  appeal,  25:  27 

repeal  advocated,  29:  59,  91 
Hotel  and  motel  rooms,  tax  on,  19:  4-10; 

29:90 
Houses  of  Refuge  Act  (1890),  21:  55 
Housing  Development  Act,  12:  71 

and    capital   financing    by    developers, 
15:58 

property  tax  exemption,  12:  15 

Housing  grants,  21:  75-80 
Hydro-Electric    Power    Commission    of 

Ontario,    12:  12;    34:  13,    14,    15; 

36:4 
accounting  practices  of,  36:  13-18 
approving  municipal  rates,  17:  53 
audits  of  municipal  utilities,  17:  45 
capital  cost  allowances  would  outweigh 

"profit",  36:  21 
"contributed  capital",  36:  18 
financing   by    funded   debt,    compared 

with  municipal  utilities,  17:  52 
fuel  cost  (1964),  34:  19 
and  local  improvement  levies,  12:  48 
payments-in-lieu,  2:  110;  12:36-41 
pricing  policies  of,  36:  17 
property  tax  exemption,  12:  30,  35-41 
provincial  guarantee  of  debt,  36:  8,  21 
special  assessment  for,  13:  69-71 

Ilsley,  J.  L.,  26:  52 

Immigrants,    numbers    to    Ontario,    4:  5 

Income: 

as  index  of  tax-paying  capacity,  1:  36-9 
money  income,  defined,  5:  7 
Income,  adjusted  broad: 
defined,  5:  29 
net  fiscal  incidence  as  percentage  of, 

T5:  8 
tax  and  benefit  rates  as  percentage  of, 
T5:  6,  T5:  7 
Income,  taxable,  property  taxes  deduct- 
ible from,  11:  87 
Income  classes  (money): 

burdens    and    benefits    of    government 
revenue  and  expenditure,  distribu- 
tion among,  5:  27-8 
distribution  of  tax  burden  among,  T5:  2 

Income  distribution: 

effects  of  income  tax,  26:  31-3 
and  government  expenditures,  1:  49 
and  motor  vehicle  charges,  30:  3 
and  taxation,  1:  29,  49 

Income  tax,  corporate,  see  Corporate  in- 
come tax 


Index 

Income  tax,  personal,  26:  1-186 
and  ability  to  pay,  1:  40-47 
advantage  over  selective  excise  taxes, 

1:57 
allocation  rules,  26:  92-110 

apportionment    procedures,    26: 92- 

101 
business   income   allocated   between 
provinces — "permanent    establish- 
ment", 26:  103-8 
business  tax,  and  varying  provincial 

rates,  26:  145-53 
net  gains  for  Alberta,  B.C.,  Ontario, 

26: 139 
residence  rule,  26:  138-44 
calculation    of    income    tax    and   Tl 

returns,  26:  173-4 
capital  gains,  26:  187-201 
collection  agreement  with  federal  gov- 
ernment, 1936,  26:  51 
and  corporate  distribution  taxes,  8:  50 
and  corporate  income  taxes,  problems, 

26:  186 
cost  to  Ontario  of  collecting  provincial 

taxes,  26:  121-2 
current  collection  agreement: 
advantages  of,  26:  123-4 
defects  of,  26:  125-36 

tax  sharing  too  limited,  26:  129-33 
definition  of  income,  10:  59 
economic  effects,  26:  8-35 

allocation  of  labour  among  employ- 
ments, 26:  21-4 

occupational  tax  differentials,  26: 
22-3 
distribution  of  income,  26:  31-3 
incidence,  26:  25-30 
on  investment  incentives,  26:  18-20 
level  of  national  income,  26:  34 
on  personal  savings,  26:  15-17,  20 
resource  allocation,  26:  35 
on  supply  of  capital  and  on  invest- 
ment, 26:  15-20 
registered  pension  plans,  26:  20n 
work  incentives,  26:  8-14 

and  standard  of  living.  26:  10 
effect   of  raising   rates    above    federal 

abatement,  26:  154-6 
and  estate  tax  correlation,  28:  225 
evaluation    of   present    fiscal    arrange- 
ments, 26:  119-56 
alternatives,  26:  119-22 

separate  administration  and  collec- 
tion of  personal  income  taxes,  26: 
121-2 

tax-sharing  arrangements,  26:  120 
income  allocation  rules,  26:  137-53 
rate  of  tax,  26:  154-6 


Chapter  numbers  are  in  bold  face;  paragraph  numbers  in  light  face.    T=Table. 
Vol.  I,  1-8;  Vol.  II,  9-23;  Vol.  Ill,  24-40 


311 


Index 


Income  tax,  personal  —  Continued 

exemptions  identical,  federally  and  pro- 

vincially,  26:  85 
expenses  should  be  deductible,  26:  178 
federal  abatement  for  provincial  taxes, 
26:  111-18 
and  the  "basic  tax",  26:  112-13 
federal,  introduction  of,  27:  11 
federal-provincial     agreements:     see 
Federal-provincial     tax     arrange- 
ments 
federal-provincial    consultation,    need 

for,  26:  125-8 
first  progressive  rate  structure,  26:  3 
general  considerations,  26:  175-86 
history  in  Ontario,  26:  37-77 

Assessment  Act  of  1904,  26:  38-41 
federal-provincial    fiscal    arrange- 
ments, 26:  64-77 
Income  Tax  Act,  1936,  26:  50-51 
municipal  income  taxation,  26:  38-49 
Ontario  not  in  1947  tax  rental  agree- 
ments, 26:  53,  55 
tax  rental  agreements,  26:  53-7 
tax-sharing  arrangements,  26:  58-63 
Wartime  Tax  Agreements,  26:  52 
incidence: 

income  derived  from  capital,  26:  28 
increased  prices,  26:  26 
increased  wages  or  salaries,  26:  26 
and  labour  supply,  26:  27,  29 
increased  abatement,  and  federal  fiscal 

policy,  8:  52 
increased  reliance  on,  26:  5-6 
insurance  companies,  preferential  treat- 
ment of,  31:  79 
and  law  of  diminishing  marginal  utility, 

1:41-7 
less   progressive    rate    structure    advo- 
cated, 26: 184 
local: 

pros  and  cons,  19:  11-21 
as  tax  on   personal   property, 
10:  22,  25,  26 
municipal,  10:  59,  74-7,  19:  11-12 
decrease  in  importance,  27:  10 
terminated,  10:  71,  75,   125 
loss  carry-over,  -back,  of  business  in- 
come, 26:  180 
necessity    of    jurisdictions   larger    than 

municipalities,  26:  48 
need  for  revision  of  structure,  8:  49-53 
Ottawa-Hull  area,  problem  of,  26:  140 
and  progressivcness  of  total  tax  system, 

5:48 
projected  increase,  8:  32,  33,  34,  36,  39 
projected   revenue   from,   6:  53,   T6:  7 
property  tax,  no  justification  for  mak- 
ing deductible,  26:  179 


Income  tax,  personal  —  Continued 
provincial  income  taxes: 

constitutional  aspects  of,  26:36 
increase,  8:  14-15,   18 
introduction  of,  27:  1 1 
municipal  sharing  of,  19:  21 
and  government  enterprises,  36:  21 
provisions    of    the    Income    Tax    Act 

1961-62,  26:  157-74 
resistance  to,  10:  40 
and  retail  sales  tax  compared: 

effect  on  economic  growth,  29:  45 
effects  on  saving  and  consumption, 

29:44 
effects  on  work  incentive,  29:  40 
relationship  to  business  cycle, 
29:  47-8 
shifting  of  burden,  26:  25-30 
should  be  general  provisions  for  aver- 
aging, 26:  185 
should  be  integrated  with  corporate  in- 
come tax,  27:  49,  74,  101 
spouses,   present   and   proposed   treat- 
ment of,  26:  181-3 
superiority  over  corporate,  1:  61 

Income  Tax  Act  (Canada): 
allocation  rules,  27:  82 
collecting  corporate  income  taxes, 

26:  89 
conflict    with    Corporations   Tax   Act, 

27:  App. 
elimination    of    conflict    between 

statutes,  27:  107-13 
and  corporate  income  tax,  27:  21,  25, 

27,  28 
and    Corporations    Tax    Act    appeals, 

27:23 
deduction    for    mining    tax,    32:  137, 

140-42 
federal    corporate    taxes,    sharing    of 

special,  27:  105 
and  the  gift  tax,  28:  210-12,  214 
"income"  not  defined,  26:  176 
and  logging  tax,  33:  45,  46 
non-resident  withholding  taxes,  27:  106 
taxation  of  inter  vivos  gifts,  28:  11 
unnecessary  exemptions,  26:  177 
weaknesses,  26:  176-86 

Income  Tax  Act  (Ontario),  26:  50-51 
appeals,  26:  171-2 
assessments,  26:  169-70 
defects  in,  26:  159-72 
farmers  and  fishermen,  averaging  pro- 
visions for,  26:  166-8 
foreign  tax  credit,  26:  163-5 
logging  tax  deduction,  26:  159-62 
provisions  of,  26:  157-74 


312 


Income  Tax  Act  (Ontario)  — Continued 
refund,  conditions  for,  25:  19 
why  omitted  from  discussion  of  admin- 
istration, 25:  4 

Income  taxes: 

international  problems,  26:  137 
provincial:  as  instrument  of  economic 

stabilization,  40:  13 
as  source  of  provincial  revenue, 

4:  46,  48 

Income  War  Tax  Act,  1917,  10:  59,  74; 
26:  4,  50 

Indian  lands,  property  tax  exemption, 
12:  84 

Institute  of  Municipal  Assessors,   10:  94 

Institutes  of  Technology  and  Trades, 
6:86 

Insurance  Act: 

no  provision  for  appeal,  25:  27 

and    taxes    on    insurance    premiums, 

31:72 

Insurance  companies: 
corporate  taxes,  27:  8,  9 
and  the  Corporations  Tax  Act,  27:  132, 

133 
income  tax  treatment,  31:  79 

Insurance    premiums,    taxes    on,    27: 4; 
31:  72-84 
description,  31:  72-5 
incidence,  31:  77-8 
justification,  31:  79-84 
in  other  provinces,  31:  73 
projected  increases  (1971-72),  8:  36,  37 
rates,  31:  72 
yield,  31:  76 

Interest  in  expectancy,  28:  92-4 

deferred  payment  of  duties,  28:  178 

Investment: 

corporate  income  tax,  economic  effects, 
27:51-8 

Investment  companies:  corporate  income 
tax,  27:  28 

Investment  credit,  corporate  income  tax, 
27:  56,  57 

Investment  Dealers  Association  of  Can- 
ada: suggested  role  in  municipal 
securities  issues,  22:  146 

Irish  Hospitals  Sweepstake,  39:  27 

Japan,    exports,    and    direct    (corporate) 

tax,  27:  63 
Jefferson,  Thomas,  on  local  government, 

23:27 


Index 

Jensen,  Jens  P.,  property  taxation  in  the 
United    States,    9:  In 

Johnson,  A.  W.,  and  J.  M.  Andrews,  on 
the  basis  and  effects  of  provincial- 
municipal  fiscal  decisions,  2:  43n 

Johnson,  J.  A.,  The  Incidence  of  Govern- 
ment Revenues  and  Expenditures, 
5:  In,  9n,  App. 

Joint  property: 

succession  duties  on,  28:  74-80 

Justice  responsibilities,  transfer  to  Pro- 
vince, 9:  90-95 

Kaldor,  Nicholas,  expenditure  tax,  1:  36 

King  V.  Caledonian  Collieries  Limited, 
32:  6n,  38;  34:  5 

Kingston,  personal  property  tax,   10:  39 

Kinsey,  Robert  K.,  on  the  Role  of  Lot- 
teries in  Public  Finance,  39:  37n 

Krzyzaniak,  M.,  effects  of  corporation 
income  tax,  27:  30n 

Labour: 

allocation  among  employments,  effect 
of  income  tax,  26:  21-4 

supply  of,  and  income  tax,  26:  27,  29 
Labour,    Department    of,    fee    revenue, 

37:  4,  T37:  1 
Labour  force: 

agricultural,  decline  in,  with  urbaniza- 
tion, 4:  8 

changes  in  composition  of,  4:  1 1 

increased  educational  needs  of,  4:  12 

occupations,    significant    shifts    in, 
4:9-10 

projection,  6:8,  11-13,   15 

public  employees,  percentages  of,  4:  19 

role  of  women,  4:11 

standard  of  living  in  Ontario,  4:  13 

and  urbanization,  4:  9 
"Land",  definition  of: 

in  1843  assessment  bill,  10:  12 

in  present  Act,  11:  17-19 

revision  proposed,  11:  24-5 
Land  transfer  tax,  31:  62-71 

conclusion,  31:  69-71 

departmental  rulings,  31:  64 

description,  31:  62-4 

incidence,  31:  65-6 

justification.  31:  67-8 

rates,  31:  63 

revenue,    1965-66.   and   administrative 
body.  T25:  1 


Chapter  numbers  are  in  bold  face:  paragraph  numbers  in  light  face.    T= Table. 
Vol.  I,  1-8;  Vol.  II,  9-23;  Vol.  Ill,  24-40 


313 


Index 

Land  Transfer  Tax  Act:  appeal  procedure, 

25:27 

Landlord  and  Tenant  Act,  14:  64 

Lands  and  Forests,  Department  of: 

as  collector  of  Crown  dues  on  timber, 

32:  32 
planting  programs,  33:  17 
and  provmcial  parks,  12:  65 
revenue  sources,  37:  4,  13,  T37:  1 
trees  sold  by,  exempt  from  sales  tax, 

29:81 

Law  enforcement:  provincial-local  respon- 
sibility for,  9:  94 

Lean,   W.,   and   B.   Goodall,   Aspects  of 
Land  Economics,  13:  20n 

Legal  fees:   as  deduction  for  succession 
duty  purposes,  28:  123 

Leonard,  W.  G.,  see  Macpherson,  L.  G. 

Licence  and  permit  fees,  municipal, 
17:  2-24 
arbitrary  fee  levels,  17:  4 
benefits-received  justification,  17:  3 
controlling  the  number  of  business  en- 
trants, 17:  23-4 
distinction  between  types  of,  17:  5-6 
distinguished  from  taxes,  17:  2 
importance  as  revenue  source,  17:  7-8 
justified  level  of,  17:  19-21 
level  of  fees,  17:  12 
necessity  or  desirability  of,  17:  13 
non-resident,  17:  22 
as  a  percentage  of  locally-derived  reve- 
nues (Ontario),  17:  9 
shifting  and  incidence,  17:  17-18 

Licence  and  permit  fees,  provincial  gov- 
ernment departments,   37:4-12, 
T37:  1 

Licence   and   permit   powers,   municipal: 
appropriate  use  of,  17:  15-16 
use  made  of,  17:  9-14 

Licences  and  permits: 

hunting  and  angling,  34:  26-32 
motor  vehicle:  see  under  Motor  vehicle 
revenues 

Life  insurance,  and  tax  base  for  succes- 
sion duty,  28:  100-102 

Life  interest: 

capital  payments  to  widow,  effects  on 

duties,  28:  201 
and  succession  duties,  28:  83-94 
valuation  of,  28:  83-4 

Life  tenant:  dying  before  duties  fully  paid, 
28:  187 

Liquor   Authority  Control    Board,   35:  7 


Liquor  Control  Act  (1927),  35:  5-8 

creation  of  Liquor  Control  Board,  35:  5 
governing  sale  and  control  of  alcoholic 

beverages,  35:  12 
gradual  liberalization  of,  35:  7-8 
see  also  Alcoholic  beverages,  revenue 

from 

Liquor  Control  Board: 

accounting  practices,  35:  57-9 
administrative  and  operating  expenses, 

35:  60-62 
compared   with    U.S.   private   liquor 

stores,  35:  60 
assets  and  depreciation,  35:  57-9 
Canadian  beer,  pricing  and  gallonage 

tax,  35:  39-40 
control  of  sales  to  minors,  35:  16 
influence   on   prices   at   point   of   pur- 
chase, 35:  30 
interest  earned  on  bank  balances, 

35:  56 
major  source  of  revenue  from  alcoholic 

beverages,  35:  1 1 
mark-up,  35:  31-4 
miscellaneous  revenue,  35:  56 
missing   from   Public   Accounts,   24:  8 
municipal    taxation,    12:  31 
new  store  locations,  35:  15 
outside  of  departmental  structure,  25:  4 
percentage  of  total  sales  of  alcoholic 

beverages,  35:  29 
and  pricing  policy,  35:  28-35 
profit,  as  source  of  provincial  revenue, 

4:47 
projected  revenue  from,  T6:  7 
responsibilities  of,  35:  5-7 
revenue  from,  as  percentage  of  P.D.P., 

6:49 
sale  and  control  of  alcoholic  beverages 

— off-premises    consumption, 

35:  13,  14-16 
sales  slips,  35:  16 

special  occasion  permits,  35:  53-4 
special  position  of  Ontario  wine,  35:  35 
Statement  of  Profit  and  Loss,  1963-64, 

T35:9 
types  of  stores,  35:  14 
wine  prices,  compared  with  other  pro- 
vinces, 35:  35 
see  also  Alcoholic  beverages,  revenue 
from 

Liquor  export  companies:  corporate  taxes, 
27:  8,   12 

Liquor  Licence  Act,  10:  125,  35:  7 
cancellation  of  licence,  35:  26-7 
governing  sale  and  control  of  alcoholic 
beverages,  35:  12 


314 


Liquor  Licence  Board: 

cancellation  of  licence,  35:  26-7 
classes  of  licences  granted,  35:  22 
creation  of,  35:  7 
duties,  35:  21 
licence  fees,  35:  45-8 

beer   gallonage,   different   scales  of, 

35:  46-7 
by  class,  35:  45 
contrast   between   spirits   and   wine, 

and  beer,  35:  46 
and  municipal  enforcement,  35:  49 
licences  and  fees  under,  35:  42-54 
licences  issued,  1948-64,  35:  23 
licensing  procedure,  35:  24-6 
outside  of  departmental  structure,  25:  4 
on-premises  consumption,  pricing 

policy  for,  35:  43-4 
responsibility  of  operator,  35:  26 
sale  and  control  of  alcoholic  beverages 
— on-premises  consumption, 
35:  21-7 
transfer  fees,  35:  50-52 

Loan  companies:  corporate  taxes, 
27:  8,  12 

Local  government: 

annual  revenue  gap,  40:  6,  7 

the  Baldwin  Act,  10:  15 

beginnings  of,  10:  2 

budgetary  and  debt  position,  projected 

(1966-75),  6:41-6 
compensation  for  narrowed  railway  tax 
base  (and  deductions  for  asylum 
inmates),  10:  51 
debt:  see  Municipal  debt 
entrusted  to  Justices  of  the  Peace,  10:  2 
expenditures, 

by  function,  4:  36-7 
gross  and  net,  4:  24-6 
more  elastic  than  revenues,  8:  43 
national  perspective,  4:  38-41 
patterns  of,  summarized,  4:  32 
related  to  estimated  P.D.P.,  4:  31 
fiscal   effects  of   recommendations, 

hypothetical  for  1966,  8:  4-7 
fiscal  position  assuming  implementation 

of  the  recommendations,  8:  43 
fiscal  year,  change  in,  and  school  grant 

payments,  20:  42 
grants  from  Province:  see  Grants,  pro- 
vincial, to  local  governments 
local  autonomy  and  equalization  pay- 
ments, 21:  29 
local    autonomy    and    fiscal    responsi- 
bility, 9:  13-21 
allocation  of  resources,  9:  5-7 


Index 

Local  government: 

local  autonomy  and  fiscal  responsibility 
—  Continued 

implications  for  taxing  powers, 

9:  38-9 
local  tax  source  access,  attributes  of, 

9:  20-21 
need  for,  9:  9 

provincial  alternatives,  9:  9-18 
organization  of,  and  the  Province, 

2:  100-108 
payments-in-lieu,  10:  99,  100,  103 
property  tax:  see  Property  tax 
provincial  financial  assistance,  growth 

of,  10:  84 
reasons  for,  23:  22 
reform,   mid-nineteenth   century,    10: 

14-17 
revenue  patterns,  4:  42-55 
as  source  of  funds  for  health  services, 

38:22 
tax  exemption  of  own  properties, 

12:  89-103 
taxation   of   mining   profits,    and   The 

Mining  Tax  Act,  32:  18 
values  of: 

access,  defined,  23:  24-6 
access  and  service,  23:  23 

conflict  between,  23:  28-9 

importance  of,  23:  28-9 
service,  defined,  23:  27 
see  also  Municipalities;  Provincial-local 

governments;  School  boards 

Local  government  structure,  reorganiza- 
tion of,  23:  1-171 
categories  of  proposals: 
internal  structure,  23:  3-4 
territorial  extent,  4:  3-4 
a  co-ordinated  program  of  local  finan- 
cial operation,  23:  166-8 
and  income  tax,  11:  142,  19:  19,  21 
internal  organization,  23:  157-68 

and  educational  finance,  23:  158-65 
larger    assessment    units,    10: 93,    94; 

13:  121-4 
local  autonomy  and  provincial  respon- 
sibility, 23:  169-71 
lower-tier    municipalities,    future    of, 
23:  155-6 
need  for  reform,  9:  47,  66,  68,  88-9; 
23:  1 
and  reduction  of  property  taxes,  11:  77 
and   school   tax   requisitioning,    20:  78 
should  obviate   need  for  equalization, 

21:28 
and  tax  billing  and  collection,   14:  89 
tax  instalment  payments,  22:  67 


Chapter  numbers  are  in  bold  face;  paragraph  numbers  in  light  face.    T=Table. 
Vol.  L  1-8;  Vol.  II,  9-23;  Vol.  Ill,  24-40 


315 


Index 


Local  government  structure,  reorganiza- 
tion of  —  Continued 
territorial  extent,  23:  5-45 

access,  service  and  the  size  of  local 
government,  23:  30-38 

ocl  hoc  service  areas,  23:  32-4 

balancing  access  and  service,  23:  31, 
35-6,  37-8,  39-45 

grass-roots  interest,  23:  16-19 

and   the   Beckett   Committee, 
23: 13-14 

multiplication  of  small  units  checked 
by  legislation,  23:  8 

post-war  developments,  23:  7-20 
annexation,  23:  8 
development  of  regional  govern- 
ment, 23:  11-12 
education,  23:  9-10 
total    acreage    increase    of   cities, 
23:77 

regionalism   and  larger   local   units, 
23:  5-6 

theoretical  considerations,  23:  21-9 

see  also  Regional  government,  sug- 
gested scheme 

Local  Improvement  Act,  12:  31;  22:  104 
apportioning  cost  of  special  capital  levy 

projects,  15:  36-43 
capital  levies  (special),  initiating  works 

financed  by,  15:4,  11-19,  34 
and  exempt  properties,  12:  12 

Local  revenue  system,  appeals,  11:  53-66; 

18:  1-24 
administrative  process,  18:  8,  9-14 
Assessment  Appeal  Boards,  18:  12,16 
assessment   appeals,    small    and   large, 

18:  7-8 
composition  of  courts  of  revision,  18: 

9-10 
conclusions,  18:  24 
contesting  validity  of  assessment 

methods,  18:  6 
costs  and  time  limits,  18:  20 
equalization  appeals,  18:  22 
existing  procedures,  18:  2-8 
judicial  process,  18:  15-19 
questions  of  fact  and  of  law,  18:  3,  5, 

15 
right  to  examine  assessment  material, 

18:  13 
rights  of,  11:  56-64 

other  rights  of  appeal,  18:  21-3 
sickness  or  poverty   plea,   18:  23 
size  of  jurisdictions,  18:  1 1 
specialization  of  judges,  18:  18-19 

Local    revenue   system,    introduction    to, 
9:  1-104 

Local  Roads  Boards  Act: 
assessors,  13:  39 


Local  Roads  Boards  Act:  —  Continued 
assessment,  basis  of,  13:  40 
and  the  assessment  of  property,  13:  37, 

38 
transferring  the  assessment  provisions 

to  the  Assessment  Act,   13:  41-5 

Local  sales  taxes,  19:  22-34 

Logging  tax: 

and   Ontario    and    federal    income 

taxes,  26:  159-62 
revenue,    1965-66,   and   administrative 
body,  T25:  1 

Logging  Tax  Act,  33:  1,  2,  40-45 
and  corporate  income  tax,  27:  27 
historical  background,  33:  40 
logging  income,  definition,  33:  41-2 
refund,  conditions  for,  25:  19 
tax  base  and  tax  credit,  33:  41-5 

Loss  carry-over,  -back,  as  income  tax 
deduction,  27:  100 

Lotteries,  39:  2,  24-39 
conclusions,  39:  39 
description,  39:  24-8 
economic  consequences,  39:  31-2 
history  of,  39:  26-8 
justification  for,  39:  29-30 
moral  question  raised,  39:  29 
only  incidence  in  Canada,  39:  28 
potential  yield,  39:  33-8 
yield,  factors  tending  to  deflate,  39:  38 

McGillivray,  Mr.  Justice,  38:  58 

McKay,  W.  S.,  The  Assessor's  Guide, 
10:63n;  11:  18n;  12:  168n 

Maclennan,  Mr.  Justice  James,  10:  35,  60 

Maclennan  Commission,  see  Ontario 
Assessment  Commission  (1900) 

Macpherson,  L.  G.,  and  W.  G.  Leonard, 
municipal  accounting  in  Canada, 
14:  4n 

Manitoba: 

administration  of  justice,  responsibility 
for,  9:91 

amusement  taxes,  31:  22 

assessment    a   provincial   function, 
13:  117 

Assessment  and  Taxation  Commission, 
Report  of — and  single  property 
tax,  10:  70 

business  tax  in,  11:  151 

business  tax  optional  instead  of  per- 
sonal property  tax,  10:  38 

corporate  income  tax,  27:  2 

federal  hospital  operating  grants,  com- 
pared  with  per-capita   income, 
38:  37 


316 


Index 


Manitoba:  — Continued 
forest  resources,  tenure  charges  (1964), 

33:  10,   11 
home-owner  grants,  11:  83,  86 
income  tax,  personal,  27:  1 1 
adoption,  26:  3,  48 
collection    agreements   with    federal 

government,  26:  51 
higher  provincial  tax  rates,  difficul- 
ties of,  26:  145,  146 
1962  tax  rates,  26:  72 
mineral    production,    value,    1966, 

T32:5 
mining  lands  tax,  T32:  9;  32:  145 
mining  profits  tax,  rates  of,  compared 

with  Ontario,  32:  124,   126 
mining  tax: 

tax  base,  32:  25-31  passim 

tax  rates  and  basic   exemption, 

32:  32,  33 
type  of,  32:  24 
motor  vehicle  fuel,  tax  rate  on,  30:  7 
motor  vehicle  licensing  reciprocity  with 

Ontario,  30:  60 
motor  vehicle  registration  fees  (1964), 

T30:4 
municipal  revenue  derived   from  per- 
mits  and   licences,    17:  7 
poll  tax,  use  of,  T16:  1;  16:  5 
retail  sales  tax  in,  29:  18 

proposal  to  tax  services,  29:  85 
Royal  Commission  on  Local  Govern- 
ment Organization   and   Finance: 
state  of  assessing,  13:27,  116 
instalment  tax  billing,  14:  41 
the  poll  tax,  16:  5 

and  reassessment  procedure,  13:  130 
surtax,  reduction  of,  26:  155 
succession  duty,  introduction  of,  28:  48 
tobacco  tax,  31:  5,  7,  13 
welfare,    introduction   of  mothers' 

allowances,  21:  37 
wine  prices,  T35:  5 
see  also  Provinces 

Marshall,  Alfred,  on  diminishing  marginal 
utility,  1:  41 

Maryland:  farm  land,  preferential  assess- 
ment of,  9:  70 

Masten,  J.  A.,  in  Re  Bayack,  11:  50n 

Mayo,  Henry  B.,  23:  16 

Medical  care:  see  Hospital  and  medical 
care,  financing  of 

Medical  Carriers  Incorporated,  38:  16 


Medical  Research  Council,  38:  20 

Medical  Services  Insurance  Act,  38:  7,  16 

Medical  Services  Insurance  Council, 
38:  16 

Memory  Gardens  vs.  Township  of  Water- 
loo, 12:  106n 

Michigan: 

race  tracks  tax  rate,  31:  44 
tobacco  tax,  31:  7 

Mickle,  G.  R.,  32:  4n 

calculation  of  nickel  allowance,  32:  88 

Mill,  John  Stuart: 

against  benefits  principle  of  taxation, 

1:26 
direct  and  indirect  taxes,  30:  28 
on  liberty,  1:  13 
on  local  institutions,  23:  26,  27 

Mines,  revenue  from: 
Crown  leases,  32:  153-6 
Mining  Act,  32:  143-52 
Mining  Tax  Act,  32:  2-50 
mining  tax,  deductibility  of,  for  income 

tax  purposes,  32:  137-42 
problem  of  constitutionality,  32:  6,  34 
proposed  tax  system,  32:  51-142 

administration  and  appeals, 
32:  131-6 

base,  32:  53 

basic  exemption,  32:  63-4 

compared  with  present  mining  tax, 
T32:7 

compared  with  present  Ontario,  Que- 
bec, Manitoba  rates,  32:  126 

depletion  allowance,  32:  91-3 
rejection  of,  32:  92-3 

depreciation  allowance,  32:  94-5 

Emergency  Gold  Mining  Assistance, 
32:67-71 

exploration  and  development  expen- 
ditures, 32:  109-17 

general  outline,  32:  51-62 

iron  ore  smelted  in  Canada,  exemp- 
tion of,  32:  72-3 

integrated  iron  mine  and  steel  mill, 
32:57 

interest    and    financing   costs, 
32:  100-101 

investment  allowance,  32:  74-81,  101 
determination  of,  32:  78-81 
rate  of,  32:  77 

Mines  Profits  Tax,  32:  53ff 

Mines  Services  tax,  32:  53ff 

mining  losses,  32:  118-21 

municipal  taxes,  32:  97-9 

new  mines,  exemption  for,  32:  65-6 


Chapter  numbers  are  in  bold  face;  paragraph  numbers  in  light  face.    T= 
Vol.  I,  1-8;  Vol.  II,  9-23;  Vol.  Ill,  24-40 


= Table. 


317 


Index 


Mines,  revenue  from: 

proposed  tax  system  —  Continued 
processing   allowance,   32:  82-90 

criticism  of  present  form,  32:  83-7 
rate  of  tax,  economic  and  fiscal  con- 
siderations, 32:  122-'^0 
royalties  and  rentals,  32:  102-8 
a    two-stage    tax,    32:  52 
unprocessed  ore,  32:  54-6 
working  expenses,  32:  96 
revenue   structure   in  other  provinces, 

32:  23-33 
Supplementary     Revenue     Act,     1907 

amendment,  10:  71 
tax  rates,   compared   with   other   pro- 
vinces, 32:  33 

Mines    Profits    Tax,    proposed,    12:  225, 
226,  235,  32:  53fl' 
projected  increase,  8:  36 

Mines  Services  Tax,  proposed,  12:  225-7, 
233;  32:53fT 

Mining  Act,  32:  143-52 
acreage  tax,  32:  143-52 

historical  background,  32:  143 
justification,  32:  146-51 
recommendation,   32:  152 
similar    taxes   in   other   provinces, 

32:  144-5 
Crown  leases,  32:  153-6 
and  property  tax  exemption,  12:  14 
revenue,    1965-66    and    administrative 
body,  T25:  1 

Mining    municipalities,    provincial    pay- 
ments  to,    10:71-3;    12:175-235; 
32:  33,41-4 
alternative  solutions,  12:  228-32 
the  Bondett  formula,  12:  228-9 
criticism  of  present  system, 
12:  191-204 

complicated  and  capricious  form- 
ula, 12:  198-204 

no  allowance  for  price  fluctua- 
tions, 12:  200 

inadequacy  of  payments,  12:  193-4 
over-recognition  of  non-resident 
miners  working  in  municipality, 
12:  195-7 

varying    needs    of    municipalities 
not  considered,  12:  191-2 
financing  of,   12:  225-7 
formula  for,  12:  179-87 
adjusted  mill  rate,  12:  182 
amount  and  adjustments,   12:  183-7 
amounts  paid  under  present  system, 

12:  188-90 
"municipal  mines  assessment", 
12:  179-81 


Mining  municipalities,  provincial  pay- 
ments to  —  Continued 
mining  properties  exempt  from   local 
taxation,   12:  233-5 
power  to  pay  not  less  than  tax  on 
mining  otherwise  leviable  under 
Assessment  Act,  12:211 
present  system,  12:  178 
proposed  formula,  12:  205-20 

effect    on    level    of    payments,    12: 

221-4 
limitation  of  payment  to  one-half  of 

municipal  budget,  12:  210 
relief  when  payment  less  than  prior 

year's  payment,  12:  212-17 
summary  and  recommendations,  12: 
218-20 

Mining  properties: 

assessed  at  value  of  farm  lands,  10:  30, 

55,  71 
business  tax,  11:  175-7 

not  feasible  to  treat  like  other  prop- 
erty, 11:  176 
exempt  from  local  taxation,   12:    175, 
177,  233-5 
see  also  Mining  municipalities,  pro- 
vincial payments  to 
taxation  of,  10:  71-3 

Mining  tax: 

compared  with  proposed  mining  tax 
system,  T32:  7 

criticism,  32:  37 

distinguished  from  royalty,  32:  38 

incidence,  32:  45-50 

justification  of  profits  tax,  32:  34-44 

mining  losses,  no  provision  for  carry- 
over and  -back,  32:  118 

no  rate  increases  proposed  in  profits 
tax,  8:  18 

Mining  Tax  Act,  32:  2-50 

administration  and  appeals,  32:   19-22 

compared  with  taxes  of  other  prov- 
inces, 32:  23-33 

computation  of  tax,  32:  16-18 
and  The  Assessment  Act,  32:  18 

deductions  from  gross  revenue  allowed, 
32:  4,  13,  15 

deductions  from  gross  revenues  not 
allowed,  32:  13,  15 

and  Emergency  Gold  Mining  Assist- 
ance Act,  32:   13,  14 

historical  background,  32:  1-7 

justification — payments  to  mining  mu- 
nicipalities, 32:  41-4 

The  Kinf^  vs.  Caledonian  Collieries 
Ltd.,  32:  6,  38 

method  of  appraising  ore,  32:  10-12 

Mine  Assessor,  functions  of,  32:  10-12, 
19,  21,  131 
criticisms  of,  32:  85-7,  132 


318 


Mining  Tax  Act  —  Continued 
and  municipalities,  10:  108 
present  revenue  structure,  32:  8-22 
refund,  conditions  for,  25:  19 
revenue  from,  1960-65,  32:  7 
revenue,    1965-66,   and   administrative 

body,  T25:  1 
tax  base,  32:  9-15 
taxable  mines,  32:  8 
"value  at  pit's  mouth",  32:  4,  10-11,  86 

Moffatt,  H.  P.,  on  independent  and  de- 
pendent school  bodies,  23:  161 
Monetary  policy: 

as  instrument  of  economic  policy,  3: 

•      11-13 
prerogative  of  federal  government,  3: 
13,  29 

Monopolists,  and  corporate  income  tax, 
27:  33 

Montreal: 

business  tax,  10:  38 
end  of  fiscal  year,  14:  21 
retail  sales  tax  in,  19:  24;  29:   11,  14 
Moore,   Milton  A.,   forestry  tenure   and 

taxes  in  Canada,  33:  28n 
Morgan,  John  S.,  on  local  administration 

of  public  welfare,  23:  88,  90 
Mortmain  and  Charitable  Uses  Act,  and 

corporate  tax,  27:  120,  123 
Motor    Vehicle   Accident   Claims   Fund, 

30:  55 
Motor  Vehicle  Fuel  Tax  Act: 

collection  and  control,  30:  12,  14-15 
definition  of  motor  vehicle  fuel,  30:  1 1 
exemption  and  refunds,  30:  22,  23 
no  provision  for  appeal,  25:  27 
revenue,    1965-66,   and    administrative 
body,  T25:  1 
Motor  vehicle  revenues,  30:  1-109 
allocation  of  road  costs,  30:  2-3 

P         alternative  revenue  sources,  30:  73-81 
municipal  licensing,  30:  80-81 
toll  facilities,  30:  74-9 

and   road-building   decisions,    30: 
77-9 
categories  of  motor  vehicles,  30:  99 
fuel  taxes  v^.  weight-distance  taxes,  30: 

108-9 
incidence  of  motor  vehicle  charges,  30: 
62-73 
burden    of    fees    among    income 

classes,  30:  70-72 
commercial  vehicles,  30:  64,  66-8 
fuel    tax,    burden    among    income 

groups,  30:  69 
private  passenger  cars,  30:  64,  65 


Index 

Motor  vehicle  revenues  —  Continued 
and  income  redistribution,  30:  3 
interprovincial  licensing  reciprocity,  30: 

60-61 
licences  and  permits,  30:  31-61 

appropriate    relationship    between 

public   and   private   vehicle  fees, 

30:  53-4 
bases  for  rate  structure,  30:  35-6 

in  other  provinces,  30:  37 
bus  licences,  30:  43-4 
driver    and    chauffeur    licences   and 

learner  permits,  30:  55-6 
interprovincial   comparison,    1964 

registration  fees,  30;    37-8 
miscellaneous  charges,  30:  57-9 
motorcycle  licences,  30:  45 
passenger  vehicle  licences,  30:  35-8 

recommendation,  30:   107 
projected  revenue  from,  6:  52,  T6:  7 
public  commercial  vehicle  fees  and 

public  vehicle  fees,  30:  46-54 
and  rising  highway  expenditures,  6: 

98,  99 
as  source  of  provincial  revenue,  4: 

47 
truck  and  trailer  licences,  30:  39-42 
motor    vehicle    charges,    distribution 

among  road  users,  30:  97-109 
allocation  of  charges,  30:  98-103 
appropriate  relationship  between  pri- 
vate and  public  vehicle  shares,  30: 

102-3 
fixed  and  variable  charges,  30:  104-9 
"incremental  cost"   method  of  cost 

allocation,  30:  98-103,   104,  106, 

109 
relation  to  road  costs,  30:  82-96 
conclusions,  30:  96 
direct  capital  and  maintenance  costs, 

30:  83,  84-8 
financing  road  costs,  30:  90-95 
"social  costs"  of  roads,  30:  83,  89 
user  and  non-user  shares,  30:  91-6 
revenue  from  fuel  taxes  compared  with 

revenue    from    licences    and   per- 
mits, 30:  105-6 
sources  of,  30:  5-81 
see  also  Fuel  taxes:  Gasoline  tax 

Municipal  Act: 

apportioning  cost  of  special  capital  levy 

projects,  15:  36-43 
assessors,  appointment  of,  13:  39 
borrowing  beyond  the  year,  22:  15,  102 
and   capital    financing   by    developers, 

15:  58 


Chapter  numbers  are  in  bold  face;  paragraph  numbers  in  light  face.    T=Table. 
Vol.  I,  1-8;  Vol.  II.  9-23;  Vol.  Ill,  24-40 


319 


Index 


Municipal  Act:  —  Continued 

capital  levies  (special) — initiating  works 
financed  by,  15:  4,  20-25,  34 

1849,  10:  15;  11:  209 

1866,  10:  25 

and  revenue-earning  enterprises,  17:  32 

on  sewage  service  rates,  17:  47 

statutory  limit  on  total  current  borrow- 
ings, 22:  11-12 

and  subdivision  agreements,  15:  73 

Municipal  Affairs,  Department  of: 
assessment  administration,  13:  35 
Assessment    Branch,    appropriate    role 

of,  13:  119 
assessment  manual,  13:  98,   101,   108- 

15 
assessors,  licensing  of,  13:  39 
and  levying  of  taxes  by  mining  munici- 
palities, 12:  175 
and    municipal    borrowing,    22:     117, 

129-32 
municipal  reserves,  regulation  of,  22: 

8-9 
Ontario  Municipal  Board  fees  revenue, 

37:  4,  T37:  1 
position    regarding    subdivision    agree- 
ments, 15:  71-9 
property  taxes: 

agreement  for  payment  of  arrears, 

14:  85 
taxes  written  off,  14:  86 
Provincial  Assistance  to  Municipalities, 

Boards  and  Commissions,  21:  3,  5 
reform  in  progress,  13:  89-92 
and    revenue-earning    enterprises,    17: 

43-5 
and  the  spread  of  regional  government, 

23:   12 
and  tax  arrears  certificate  registrations, 

14:  79 
and  taxation  of  mining  profits,  32:  18 
transportation     and     communications, 

proposed  assessment  of,  13:  83 

Municipal  debt,  22:  1-148 
borrowed  funds,  sources  of: 

market-place  alternative,  22:  56-61 
New   York   market,   22:    60,   87, 
143 

sinking-fund  debentures,  22:  61 
ways  of  disposing  of  debentures, 
22:  56-7 
senior  governments,  22:  38-55 
Central     Mortgage    and    Housing 

Corporation,  22:  42-5 
government    loan    funds,    signifi- 
cance of,  22:  54-5 
Municipal  Development  and  Loan 

Act.  22:  40-41 
Ontario    Education    Capital    Aid 
Corporation,  22:  53 


Municipal  debt, 

borrowed  funds,  sources  of: 

senior  governments  —  Continued 
Ontario   Municipal   Improvement 

Corporation,  22:  46-9 
Ontario    Water    Resources    Com- 
mission, 22:  50-52 
borrowing    "beyond    the    year",    and 
length  of  council  terms,  22:    15, 
89,  102 
borrowing     requirements,     procedures 

and  control,  22:  3-37 
burden  (net,  local),  projected,  40:  3 
capital  borrowing  controls,  evaluation 

of,  22:  70-148 
capital  borrowing,  procedure  and  con- 
trols, 22:  28-37 
capital  budgeting,  22:  36-7 
forms  of  debt,  22:  31-3 
referendum,  22:  29-30,  124-6 
capital  borrowing,  defined,  22:  15 
capital    borrowing    requirements,    22: 
15-27 

capital  construction,  22:  22 
debt  classified  by  main  purpose,  22: 

26-7 
heavy  dependence  on,  22:   18,  21-5 
limitations  on,  22:   15,  17 
total  capital  requirements,  22:  22-3 
criteria  for  municipal  debentures,  22: 

119 
current  borrowing  controls — evaluation 

of,  22:  62-9 
current  borrowing  procedures  and  con- 
trol, 22:  10-14 
statutory  limit,  22:  11-12 
current    borrowing    requirements,    22: 
3-8 
capital  outlays,  22:  7 
debt  charges,  22:  6 
influenced  by  tax  billing  and  collec- 
tion system,  22:  5 
reserves,  22:  8-9 
debentures,  forms  of,  22:  32-3 
effect  of  recommendations,  8:  7 
effect    of    recommendations    and    in- 
creased school  grants,  8:  23 
heavy  reliance  on,  pros  and  cons,  22: 

74-87 
importance   of   flow  of  revenues,   22: 

62-8 
improving    debenture    marketing,    22: 

142-8 
increase  since  1939,  4:  56 
increasing,  22:  24-7,  71,  73 
level  of  debt,  definition,  22:  110-14 
limits  of  capital  borrowing,  22:  71-89 
maximum    terms,    by    type    of    asset, 

22:91 
post-war  trends,  4:  61-5 


320 


Index 


Municipal  debt  —  Continued 
ratios,  4:  57 

as  percentage  of  P.D.P.,  stabilizing, 
40:  6-8 
and  referendum  for  capital  borrowing, 

22:  30 
in  relation  to  P.D.P.,  6:  44-6;  22:  72 
school  boards  and  public  library  boards, 

22:  28-9 
screening  of  proposed  borrowing,  22: 
115-26 
government    screening,    22:  116-17, 

121-3 
referendum,  22:  124-6 
underwriters'  screening,  22:  118-20, 
121-3 
secular  growth  to  1975,  40:  6 
tax  collection  systems,  improvement  of, 

22:67 
ways  of  reducing  dependence  on,  22: 
90-109 
borrowing    beyond    the    year,    new 

definition,  22:  102,  106 
capital  items,  narrow  definition  of, 

22:98 
capital  items  from  revenue,  22:  99- 

100,   107-9 
commuted  local  improvement  levies, 

22:  104,  106 
down  payments,  22:  101 
non-recurring  revenues,  22:  105 
reducing  debt  charges,  22:  95,  106 
reserve  funds,  use  of,  22:  97,  106 
reserves,  use  of,  22:  103 
selected   method,  22:  106-9 
shortened  term,  22:  94,  106 
sinking-fund  surpluses,   22:  96,    106 
what  borrowing  should  be  done  through 
government   agencies?  22:  133-41 
what  provincial  authority  should  con- 
trol borrowing?  22:  127-41 

Municipal  Development  and  Loan  Act, 
22:  40-41 

Municipal  expenditure: 

benefit  rates  by  money-income  classes, 

5:  34-7 
current  and  capital  projection,  6:  32-6 
gross,  trends  in,  4:  30 
gross  and  net,  divergence  between,  4: 

25-6 
net,  rate  of  change,  4:  27 
net,  gained  by  residents  of  Ontario,  5: 

42-3 
net  real,  4:  28 
net  real  per  capita,  4:  29 
projection,  6:  31-6 
roads,  30:  86,  88 


Municipal  finance,  3:  55-7 

counter-cyclical  fiscal   measures,  not 

realistic,  3:  55 
sources  of  data  on,  9:  96-104 
weakness  of  figures  used,  4:  22 
Municipal  Grants  Act  (Canada): 

and   federal   Crown  corporations   and 

agencies,  12:  80 
federal   grants-in-lieu,    12:  76-80 

properties  excluded  from,  12:  79 
and  properties  of  foreign  governments, 

12:  83 
and  property  exemptions,   12:  12 
Municipal  revenues: 
gross: 

breakdown  of,  4:51 
since  1939,  4:  43 
net,  rate  of  increase,  4:  45 
non-tax,  17:  1-54 
definition,  17:  1 

licence  and  permit  fees,  17:  2-24 
revenue-earning    enterprises,    17: 

31-54 
user  fees  and  charges,  17:  25-30 
poll  tax,  16:  3 
possible  new  sources,  19:  1-34 

hotel  and  motel  rooms  tax,  19:  4-10 
local  income  tax: 

administration  of,  19:  16-17 
and  corporate  taxes,  19:  15 
essentially  a  grant  program,  19:  20 
implementing  of,  19:  14 
yield,  19:  18 
local  sales  taxes,  19:  22-34 
motor  vehicle  licences,  30:  80 
taxes  based  on  income,  earning,  etc., 
19:  11-21 
projection,  6:  22-7 
property  tax:  see  Property  tax 
sources,  16:  9 

Municipal    Tax    Assistance    Act    (1952), 

10:  85;  11:  60 
payments-in-lieu,  12:  31,  33 
properties  excluded   from  taxation  or 

grants-in-lieu,  12:  34 
and  property  exemptions,  12:  12 

Municipal   Tax   Exemption   Act   (1920), 
10:69 

Municipal  Unconditional  Grants  Act,  10: 
86-7;  21:  59,  94-5,  98 
hospital  care  of  indigents,  38:  54 

Municipalities: 

community  service  facilities,  17:  40-41 
enforcement  of  liquor  Acts,  35:  49 
financial  flexibility,  limitations,  4:  62 
fiscal  year,  14:  2-22 


Chapter  numbers  are  in  bold  face;  paragraph  numbers  in  light  face.    T= 
Vol.  I,  1-8;  Vol.  II,  9-23;  Vol.  Ill,  24-40 


= Table. 


321 


Index 


Municipalities:  — Continued 

grants:  see  Grants,  provincial,  to  muni- 
cipalities 
growth,  4:  21 
hospital   care    for    indigents,    cost   of, 

38:  54-5 
hospital  construction,  grants  for,  38:  27 
income  assessment  and  total  assessment 

for  selected  years,  19:  12 
income  taxes,  26:  1,  38-49 
problems,  26:  44-5 
small  yield,  26:  42-5 
levy  taxes  for  other  bodies,  10:  112-14 
licence  rates   for  commercial  vehicles 

and  trolley  buses,  30:  41,  44 
and  the  Mining  Tax  Act,  10:  108 
motor  vehicle  licensing,  30:  80-81 
net  fiscal  incidence,  pattern  of,  5:  46 
and  provincial  park  roads,  12:  66 
recreational  enterprises,  17:  42 
revenue-earning  enterprises: 
classification,  17:  32 
desirable  revenue  policies,  17:  43-54 
description    and    importance,    17: 

31-42 
earnings    turned    over    to    munici- 
palities, 17:  50 
problem  of  rates,  17:  47-9 
special-purpose  bodies,  17:  34 
types  of,  17:  35-42 
rural,    problem    of   recreational   prop- 
erties, 11:  126-7 
and  sales  tax  exemptions,  29:  77,  78 
should  have  right  to  appeal  payments- 

in-lieu,  11:  60 
status  of: 

and  health  grants,  21:  69-70,  72 
and  road  grants,  21:  20-22 
surpluses  of  electrical  utilities,  17:  51-2 
tax  imbalance,  9:  69-89 

ways  of  overcoming,  9:  76,  77-89 
equalizing  grants  from  the  Province, 

9:  76,  84-7 
larger  municipalities,  9:  76,  88-9 
municipal  tax  pooling,  9:  76,  77-81 
tax  ratios,  residential-farm-business, 
adjustment  of,  9:  76,  82-3 
tax  rates  by  income  classes,  5:  30-31, 

33 
taxation,  and  mining  properties,  32:  53, 

58,  59,  97-9 
urban  service  areas,  11:  209-18 
utilities,  financed  by  funded  debt,  com- 
pared with  Ontario  Hydro,  17:  52 
utility  operations,  17:  35-9 
welfare,  declining  role  in,  21:  36-9 
.see  also  Local  government 

Municipality    of    Metropolitan    Toronto 
Act,  13:  39 
property  tax  exemption,  12:  16 


Museums: 

and  sales  tax  exemptions,  29:  78 

Musgrave,  Richard  A.: 
on  double  taxation,  1:  37n 
"Eftects   of   Tax   Policy   on   Private 
Capital  Formation",  26:  16n 

Musgrave,  Richard  A.,  and  Peggy  Brewer 
Richman,  on  allocation  aspects, 
domestic  and  international,  27: 
66n 

National  Health  and  Welfare,  Depart- 
ment of,  38:  20 

National  Health  Grants,  38:  45,  47 

National  Housing  Act,  22:  43,  45 

and   capital   financing    by    developers, 

15:58 

National  Revenue,  Department  of,  Cus- 
toms and  Excise  Division:  and  pro- 
vincial retail  sales  taxes,  29:  121 

Natural  gas,  production  of,  34:  2-9 
lease  rentals  and  royalties,  34:  7-9 
and  Mining  Tax  Act,  34:  3,  4-5,  8,  9 

ultra  vires,  34:  5 
profits  tax  recommended,  34:  6,  9 
provincial  revenue  derived  from,  34:  3 
total,  34:  2 

Natural  resources,  revenue  from,  34:  1-32 
"economic  rent",  32:  40;  33:  25;  34:  6 
fish  and  wildlife,  34:  25-32 
natural  gas,  production  of,  34:  2-9 
oil  production,  34:  10-11 
as  source  of  provincial  revenue,  4:  46 
water  power  rentals,  34:  12-24 
see  also  Mines;  Forest  resources 

Navy  League  of  Canada,  property  tax 
exemption,  12:  13,  105 

Netzer,  Dick,  Economics  of  the  Property 
Tax,  9:61n;  13:  15,  20n,  98 

New  Brunswick: 

administration  of  justice,  responsibility 

for,  9:91 
amusements  tax,  31:  22 
business  tax,  11:  151 
corporation  taxes,  27:  2,  6 
federal  hospital  operating  grants,  com- 
pared   with    per-capita    income, 
38:  37 
forest  resources,  revenues  from,  33:  35 
Crown  dues,  33:  12 
rental  based  on  area,  33:  28 
rental  based  on  inventory,  33:  27 
local  reliance  on  property  tax,  10:  In 
meals  tax,  29:  54 
mineral  production,  value,  1966,  T32:  5 


322 


New   Brunswick: — Continued 
mining  tax: 

tax  base,  32:  25-3 1  passim 

tax  rates  and  basic  exemption,  32: 

32-3 
type  of,  32:  24 
motor  vehicle  fuel,  tax  rates  on,  30:  7 
motor  vehicle  licensing  reciprocity  with 

Ontario,  30:  60 
motor  vehicle  registration  fees  (1964), 

T30:4 
municipal  licensing  of  motor  vehicles, 

30:  80 
municipal  revenue  derived   from  per- 
mits and  licences,  17:  7 
poll  tax,  use  of,  16:  3,  5 
problem  of  over-mature  stands  of  tim- 
ber, 33:  18,  27 
retail  sales  tax  in,  29:  15 

rate,  29:  98 
Royal    Commission    on    Finance    and 
Municipal  Taxation,  16:  5 
and  administration  of  justice,  9:  9 In 
on  instalment  tax  billing,  14:  41 
on  the  poll  tax,  16:  15 
and  reassessment  procedure,  13:  130 
on  state  of  assessing,  13:  27,  116 
sales  tax,  production  machinery,  29:  67 
school  board  fiscal  year,  14:  21 
succession  duties,  introduction  of,  28: 

48 
tobacco  tax,  T31:  1 
wine  prices,  T35:  5 
see  also  Provinces 

New  Brunswick  Forest  Development 
Commission — stump  age  system, 
defects  of,  33:  13,  16,  18 

Newfoundland: 

administration  of  justice,  responsibility 

for,  9:  9 1 
amusements  tax,  31:  22 
business  tax,  11:  151 
corporate  income  tax,  27:  2 
federal  hospital  operating  grants  com- 
pared   with    per-capita    income, 
38:  37 
fire  insurance  tax,  31:  73 
forest  revenue: 
Crown  dues,  33:  4 
tenure  charges,  T33:  3 
meals  tax,  29:  54 

mineral  production,  value,  1966,  T32:  5 
mining  lands  tax,  T32:  9,  32:  145 
mining  profits  tax,  rates  of,  32:  124 
mining  tax: 

tax  base,  32:  25-3 1   passim 


Index 

Newfoundland: 

mining  tax:  —  Continued 

tax  rates  and  basic  exemption,  32: 

32,  33 
type  of,  32:  24 

motor  vehicle  fuel,  tax  rates  on,  30:  7-8 

motor  vehicle  registration  fees  (1964), 
30:37 

municipal  licensing  of  motor  vehicles, 
30:  80 

municipal  revenue  derived  from  per- 
mits and  licences,  17:  7 

poll  tax,  use  of,  T16:  1 

retail  sales  tax  in,  29:  15 
rate,  29:  98 

sales  tax — production  machinery,  29: 
67 

tax  rental  agreements,  27:  13 

tobacco  tax,  T31:  1 

wine  prices,  T35:  5 

see  also  Provinces 

New  Hampshire:  lottery  yield,  39:  34-7 

New  Toronto:  partial,  graded  exemption 
of  dwelling  units,  10:  67;  11:  95, 
97 

New  York: 

power  exported  to  Ontario,  34:  19 
race  tracks  tax,  rate  of,  31:  44 
tobacco  tax,  31:  7 

New  York  City: 

hotel  and  motel  rooms  tax,  yield,  19:  5 
retail  sales  tax,  19:  22,  23 

Niagara  Bridge  Commission,  36:  4 

Niagara  Parks  Act,  15:  41 

property  tax  exemption,  12:  16 

Niagara  Parks  Commission,  36:  4 

Niskanen,  W.  A.:  on  consumer  demand 
for  liquor,  35:  79n 

Northern  Broadcasting  Co.  vs.  District  of 
Mountjoy,  11:  20n 

Northwest  Territories: 

mineral    production,    value,    1966, 

T32:  5 
no  federal  tax  abatement,  26:  116 
succession  duty,  introduction  of,  28:  48 

Norway,  capital  gains,  26:  193 

"Nothings",  should  be  tax-deductible, 
26:  178 

Nova  Scotia: 

administration  of  justice,  responsibility 

for,  9:91 
amusements  tax,  31:  22 


Chapter  numbers  are  in  bold  face;  paragraph  numbers  in  light  face.    T=Table. 
Vol.  I,  1-8;  Vol.  II,  9-23;  Vol.  Ill,  24-40 


323 


Index 


Nova  Scotia;  —  Continued 

corporate  income  tax,  27:  2 

federal  hospital  operating  grants,  com- 
pared with  per-capita  income, 
38:  37 

forest  revenue: 
Crown  dues,  33:  4 
tenure  charges,  T33:  3 

local  reliance  on  property  tax,  10:  In 

meals  tax,  29:  54 

mineral  production,  value,  1966, 
T32:5 

mining  acreage  tax,  T32:  9,  32:  144 

mining  tax: 

tax  base,  32:  25-3 1  passim 

tax  rates  and  basic  exemptions,  32: 

32,  33 
type  of,  32:  24 

motor  vehicle  fuel  tax,  rates  on,  30:  7 

motor  vehicle  registration  fees  (1964), 
T30:4 

municipal  revenues  derived  from  per- 
mits and  licences,  17:  7 

poll  tax,  use  of,  16:  3,  5 

Provincial  and  Municipal  Taxation 
Study,  9:  9 In 

retail  sales  tax  in,  29:  16 

sales  tax — production  machinery,  29: 
67 

succession  duties,  introduction  of,  28: 
48 

tobacco  tax,  T31:  1 

wine  prices,  T35:  5 

see  also  Provinces 

Nova  Scotia  Municipal  Bureau,  poll  tax, 
16:  10 

Oil  production,  revenue  from,  34:  10-11 

Old  Age  Assistance,  federal  abatement 
for,  26:  114,   115 

Old  Age  Assistance  Act,  and  OMSIP 
premiums,  38:  16 

Old  Age  Security  Tax,  26:  135 
and  provincial  tax  base,  26:  112 

Ontario  Assessment  Commission  (1900) 
(Maclennan  Commission),  4:  1,  4, 
66;  10:  35-6,  42,  45,  46,  106 

and  the  Assessment  Act  of  1904,  10: 
53-60  passim 

flat-rate  business  occupancy  tax,  pro- 
posed, 10:  42,  43 

on  personal  property  tax,  10:  37,  39 
alternatives  to,  10:  40 

and  special-franchise  properties,  10: 
48,  50-51 

valuation  of  special-assessment  prop- 
erties, recommendations,  13:  74, 
75 


Ontario  Cancer  Treatment  and  Research 
Foundation,  38:  11 

Ontario  Commission  on  Railway  Taxation 
(1905),  on  corporation  tax,  27:  7 

Ontario  Development  Agency,  36:  7 

Ontario  Education  Capital  Aid  Corpora- 
tion, 20:  47;  22:  53,  54,  55,  86, 
133,  136,  137,  138 

Ontario  Food  Terminal  Act,  property  tax 
exemption,  12:  16 

Ontario  Food  Terminal  Board,  36:  4 

Ontario  Foundation  Tax  Plan,  6:  38;  20: 
20,  22-59 
basic  tax  relief  grant,  29:  23,  32 
and    the    corporation    tax    adjustment 

grant,  20:  28-30 
equalization  grant,  20:  24-5,  32 
growth  need  grant,  20:  33 
improving  the  structure  of,  20:  38-59 
corporation    tax    adjustment    grant, 

20:  52-9 
pupil  load,  calculating,  20:  39-42 
recognized    extraordinary    expendi- 
ture, 20:  43-9 
regional    and    other    variations    in 
school  costs,  20:50-51 
the  present  school  grant  structure,  20: 
23-37 
advantages  of,  20:  26-7 
developments  since  1964,  20:  34-7 
attendance  growth  grant,  20:  37 
change  in  equalization  data,  20: 
35 

increased    basic    tax    relief    grant 
and  operating  cost  levels,  20:  36 
new  capital  cost  system,  20:  37 
pupil  load  based  on  average  daily 
enrolment,  20:  37 
operating  expenditures,  20:  23-30 
recognized     extraordinary    expendi- 
ture, 20:  31-3 
and    readjustment    of    residential    and 

farm  mill  rates,  20:  74 
should   incorporate   most   "stimulation 

grants",  20:  63-4 
and  vocational  school  grants,  20:  69,  70 

Ontario   Hospital   Care   Insurance   Plan, 
38:  15,  19 
contributions,  38:  65,  68-9 
and  hospital  operating  costs,  38:  43 
and  OMSIP,  integration  of,  38:76-81 
subsidization    of    premiums    recom- 
mended, 38:  74 
premium  rates,  38:  70-72 
see   also   Hospital    and    medical    care, 
financing  of 


324 


Index 


Ontario   Hospital   Services   Commission, 
12:  117;  36:6;  38:32 
hospitals  under  jurisdiction  of,  38:  10 
as  major  source  of  provincial  revenue, 

4:50 
not  adequately  reported  in  Public  Ac- 
counts, 24:  8 
outside  of  departmental  structure,  25:  4 
premiums  as  a  tax,  6:  2 
provincial   contributions    to,    6:  102-3, 

105 
reasons  for  creation  of,  38:  13-15 
and  regional  planning,  23:  104 
and  unmanageable-debt  grants,  38:  26 
see   also    Hospital    and   medical  care, 
financing  of 

Ontario  Hospitals,  operation  and  main- 
tenance of,  6:  104-5 
see   also   Hospital   and   medical    care, 
financing  of 

Ontario  Housing  Corporation,  17:  38;  21: 
78;  36:  7 
and    capital   financing   by   developers, 
15:58 

Ontario  Institute  for  Studies  in  Educa- 
tion, 20:  34,  51 

Ontario  Institute  for  Studies  in  Educa- 
tion Act,  property  tax  exemption, 
12:  16 

Ontario  Junior  Farmer  Establishment 
Loan  Corporation,  36:  6 

Ontario  Medical  Services  Insurance  Plan 

(OMSIP),  38:  19,  55 
and  O.H.C.I.P.,  integration  of,  38: 

76-81 
premium  payments,  38:  72-4 
projected  cost,  6:  106 
purpose  of,  38:  16 
subsidization  of  premium  payments,  38: 

73,  79 
see   also   Hospital    and   medical   care, 

financing  of 
Ontario  Mental  Health  Foundation  Act, 

property  tax  exemption,  12:  16 

Ontario  Municipal  Asociation: 

on  assistance  to  home-owners  on  fixed 

income,  11:  70n 
and  local  government  reform,  23:  18 

Ontario  Municipal  Board: 

appeals  of  classification  of  roads,  21:  25 
approval    of    capital    works,    15: 7-56 

passim 
approval  of  municipal  borrowing,  22: 

31-7  passim,  49,  116-17,  121,  128, 

130-32 


Ontario  Municipal  Board  —  Continued 
assessment  appeals,  18:  2-3,  4,  5 
and  capital  expenditure  for  hospitals, 

38:22 
control  of  current  borrowing,  22:  69 
dissolving  existing  police  villages,  23:  8 
and    high    school    boards,    equalized 

assessment,  20:  9 
and  separate  school  debt,  22:  110 

Ontario  Municipal  Improvement  Corpora- 
tion, 22:40,  46-9,  54,  55,  117, 
134,  135,  136;  36:  6 

and  financial  role  of  regional  govern- 
ments, 23:  143 

lending  rates,  22:  48 

projects  eligible  for  financing,  22:  46 

Ontario  Northland  Railway,  taxation  on 
railway  properties,  12:  31 

Ontario  Northland  Transportation  Com- 
mission, 36:  4 
debt  guaranteed  by  Province,  36:  8,  32 

Ontario  Parks  Integration  Board,  12:  66 

Ontario  Police  Commission  (third  annual 
report),  on  small  police  forces, 
23:  101 

Ontario  Provincial  Police,  and  provincial 
parks,  12:  65,  67 

Ontario  Racing  Commission,  31:  39 

Ontario-St.  Lawrence  Development  Com- 
mission Act,  15:  41 

Ontario  School  Trustees'  Council,  20:  66 

Ontario  Stock  Yards  Board,  36:  4 

Ontario  Universities  Capital  Aid  Corpora- 
tion, 6:  89;  36:  6 
inadequately  presented  in  Public  Ac- 
counts, 24:  10 

Ontario  Water  Resources  Commission, 
22:40,  50-52,  54,  55,  117,  134, 
135;  23:  114-15;  36:4 

and  financial  role  of  regional  govern- 
ment, 23:  143 

obligations  to,  inadequately  reported, 
22:  112 

Ontario   Water   Resources   Commission 
Act: 
capital  levies  (special),  initiating  works 

financed  by,  15:  4,  26 
property  tax  exemption,  12:  16 

"Opting-out"  formula:  see  Established 
Programs  (Interim  Arrangements) 
Act 

Ottawa-Hull  area:  implications  for  pro- 
vincial income  taxes,  26:  140 


Chapter  numbers  are  in  bold  face;  paragraph  numbers  in  light  face.    T=Table. 
Vol.  I,  1-8;  Vol.  II,  9-23;  Vol.  Ill,  24-40 

325 


Index 


Owen  Sound,  City  of,  pre-election  bud- 
geting, 14:  6-9 

Paid-up  capital,  tax  on,  27:  3,  12,  114-25 

Parish  and  Town  Officers  Act  (1793), 
10:  2n 

Parking  lots:  effects  of  proposed  changes 
in  business  tax,  11:  156 

Patterson,  H.  L.,  Significant  Economic 
Changes  in  Agriculture,  11:  196 

"Permanent  establishment",  27:  25 
definition  in  Income  Tax  Act,  26:  103 
definition  of,  and  retail  sales  tax,  29: 

114 
and  paid-up  capital  and  place-of-busi- 

ness  taxes,  27:  116,  119-20 
significance  of,  26:  137 

Perry,  J.  Harvey: 
on  the  Assessment  Act  of  1904,  10:  59n 
on  the  Report  of  the  Manitoba  Assess- 
ment and  Taxation  Commission, 
10:70 

Pipe  lines,  transmission,  special  assess- 
ment for,  13:  54-9 

Place-of-business  tax,  27:3,  12,  114-25 

Places  of  worship  and  other  religious 
property,  property  tax  exemption, 
1:67,  69,  72;  12:  119-28 

Planning  Act,  15:  2 

and   capital   work   financed   by  devel- 
opers, 15:  58 
and  subdivision  agreements,  15:  71-9 

Police  Act,  11:  215 

amalgamation    of    municipal    police 

forces,  23:  102 
capital  levies  (special)  15:  4,  33 

Police  villages,  11:208,  209,  217 
dissolution  of,  23:  8 

Poll  tax,  10:  125;  16:  1-18 
alternatives,  16:  6 
conclusions,  16:  17-18 
economic  considerations,  16:  7-8 
extent  used  by  Canadian  municipalities, 

16:  3 
historical  background,  16:  2 
justification,  16:  9-12 
provincial  trends,  16:  5-6 
recommendation,  16:  18 
shortcomings,  16:  13-16 
use  in  Ontario,  16:  4 

Poole,  Kenyon  E.,  Sales  Tax  Economics, 
29:  23n,  38n,  49n 


Population  (Ontario),  4:  4-14 
age  distribution  of,  4:  6 
economic  activities  of,  4:  8-14 
numbers,  4:  4 
projection,  6:  8,  9-10 
shitt  in,  and  increased  total  acreage  of 

cities,  23:  7 
standard  of  living,  4:  13 
urbanization,  increased,  4:  4-5,  7 
and  the  pressures  of  governments, 

4:7 

Port    Arthur,    telephone  system,    15:  31; 
17:36 

Postage    stamps:    sales    tax    exemption, 
29:  81 

Power  Commission  Act,  11:  60,  165,  215; 
13:69 
amendments  to,  10:  85 
cost  of  power,  and   accounting  prac- 
tices, 36:  14-16 
and  Hydro  properties,  12:  43 
pricing  policies  of,  36:  17 
and  property  exemptions,  12:  12 
and    the   tax   position  of   Hydro,    12: 
36-41 

Power  companies,  special  assessment  for, 
13:  50-53 

Prairie  provinces,  farms,  preferential  tax 
treatment,  9:  70 

Prime  Minister,  Department  of,  incidental 
revenue,  37:  2,  13 

Prince  Edward  Island: 

administration  of  justice,  responsibility 
for,  9:91 

amusements  tax,  31:  22 

business  tax,  11:  151 

corporation  taxes,  27:  2,  6 

federal  hospital  operating  grants,  com- 
pared with  per-capita  income, 
38:  37 

fire  insurance,  no  extra  tax  on,  31:  73 

income  tax,  personal: 
adoption  of,  26:  3,  48 
collection    agreement    with    federal 
government,  26:  51 

interprovincial  movements  of  persons, 
26:  138 

meals  tax,  29:  54 

motor  vehicle  fuel,  tax  rates  on,  30: 
7,  8 

motor  vehicle  registration  fees  (1964) 
T30:4 

municipal  revenue  derived  from  per- 
mits and  licences,  17:  7 

poll  tax,  use  of,  T16:  1;  16:  5 

retail  sales  tax,  29:  16 

sales  tax — production  machinery,  29: 
67 


326 


Prince  Edward  Island :  —  Continued 
school  board  fiscal  year,  14:  21 
succession  duty,  introduction  of,  28:  48 
tobacco  tax,  131:  1 
wine  prices,  T35:  5 
see  also  Provinces 

Production  machinery,  retail  sales  tax  on, 
29:  67-8 

Prohibition,  difficulties  of,  35:  4 

Property,  real  and  personal: 

difficulty  of  distinguishing,  10:  97 
distinction    between.    Assessment    Act 
of  1850,  10:  18 

Property,  recreational,  tax  treatment  of, 
11:  123-30 

Property,    special-franchise,    valuation 
problem,  10:48-51 

Property  tax,  personal,  10:  20-22,  26;  11: 

4-7 
abandonment  of,  10:  37-41 
criticism  of,  10:  33-4,  37-9 
Maclennan    Commission,    alternatives 

to,  10:40 

Property  tax,  real: 

appeals:    see    Local    revenue    system, 

appeals 
assessment:     see    Assessment,    real 

property 
base,  11:  3-26 

assessable  property,  defined,  11:  16- 

25 
definitions,  10:  97-109 
personal  property,  exclusion  of,  11: 

3-7 
property  valuation,  terms  and  condi- 
tions  governing,    10:  104-9 
site  value  taxation,  10:  70;  11:  8-15 
basic  issues  and  policy  proposals,  11: 

1-218 
basic  local  tax,  2:  87-8 
business  assessment  and  taxation,  10: 

110-11;  11:  131-64 
collections,  10:  121-3;   14:  1-89 

administrative  considerations,  14: 

84-9 
annual  timetable,  14:  22 
competing  claims,  14:  84 
conclusions,  14:  87-9 
experience  of  Ontario  municipalities, 
14:  23-32 

business  taxes,  14:  31-2 
current  collections  by  classes  of 
municipalities,  14:  26,  28-9 
inter-year  comparisons,  14:  25 
taxes  outstanding  as  percentage  of 
year's  levy,  14:  27,  30 


Index 

Property  tax,  real :  —  Continued 
factors  affecting,  14:  33-6 

number  ot  mstalments,  14:  36 
instalment  payment  of  taxes, 

14:  37-47,  51,  52 

and  municipal  borrowing,  14:  42 

and  tax  delmquency,  14:  42 
the  last  resort,  14:  73-83 

sale  of  properties   for   taxes, 

14:  74-8 

tax  arrears  certificate  registrations, 

14:  79-83 
overdue  taxes,  14:  54-83 

business  tax,  responsibility  for,  14: 

60-67 

interest  and  penalties,  compound- 
ing of,  14:  58 

methods   of   enforcing:    suit,   lien 

and  distress,  14:  59-60 

penalties,  14:  54-8 

from  previous  years,  14:  56 

role  of  the  county  in  collections, 

14:  68-72 
the  municipal  fiscal  year,  14:  2-22 

alternatives  to  mid-year  budgeting, 

14:5-11 

changing  of  fiscal  year,  14:  11-21 

City  of  Owen  Sound,  pre-election 

budget,  14:  6-9 

council  spending  without  prior 

authorization,  14:  3 

County  of  Grey,  pre-election 

budget,  14:  6-9 

elections,  changing  of  time,  14:  10 

mid-year  budgeting,  14:  2-3 
payment  of  arrears,  agreement  for, 

14:  85 
prepayments,  14:  48-53 

working  funds,   accumulation  of, 

14:51 
school  and  municipal  billing,  separa- 
tion of,  14:  45 
taxes  written  ofl",  14:  86 
corporations,  problem  of  school   sup- 
port, 20:  55-7 
cost-revenue  relations,   residential   and 

business,  9:  71 
differences  in  rates  imposed  by  local 

governments,   effects  of,  9:  38-47 
differential  levies,  10:  114-18 
differential  mill  rate,  11:  68 
differential    treatment,    residential    and 

business,  9:  69,  71-6 
effective  levy,  assuming  implementation 

of  recommendations,  8:  43 
effects  of,  9:  22-68 

business  properties,  9:  34-7 
incidence,  9:  53-61 


Chapter  numbers  are  in  bold  face;  paragraph  numbers  in  light  face.    T=Table. 
Vol.  I,  1-8;  Vol.  II,  9-23;  Vol.  Ill,  24-40 


327 


Index 


Property  tax,  real : 

effects  of  —  Continued 
non-residents,  9:  48-52 

business  tax,  9:  50-52 
regressiveness,  9:  58-9 
residential   properties,    owner-occu- 
pied, 9:  31-3 
residential  rental  properties,  9:  25-30 

rate  of  tax,  higher,  9:  26-30 

rate  of  tax,  unchanged,  9:  25 
exemptions:  see  Exemptions,  property 

tax 
fiscal  effect  of  recommendations,  8:  5-7, 

9,   10,   11 
general  appraisal  of,  9:  62-8 

weaknesses  of,  9:  66 
golf  courses,  11:  185 
and  heavy  capital  borrowing,  22:  80 
history,  10:  2-95 

assessed  value  in  law  and  practice, 

10:78-81 
assessing,  improving  the  standard  of, 

10:91-5 
Assessment  Act  of  1850,  10:  17-23 

amendments  to,  10:  19-22 
Assessment  Act  of  1853,  10:  23 
Assessment  Act  of  1904,  10:  53-60 
the  Baldwin  Act,  10:  15 
bodies   of   inquiry,    1878-1905, 

10:  32-6 
business   assessment   alternative, 

10:  42-6 

and  the  Maclennan  Commission, 

10:  42,  43 

and  Select  Committee  proposals, 

10:  44-6 
changes,   1840's,  10:  10-13 
District  Councils  Act  of  1841,  10:  10 
early  collection  problems,  10:  8 
early  legislation,  10:  3-6 
exemption    for   certain   farm   lands, 

10:29,  116 
first,  and  optional,  business  tax, 

10:  28,  42 
late  nineteenth  century,  10:  27-36 
mining   properties,   taxation   of, 

10:  71-3 
municipal  income  tax,  10:  74-7 
Ontario   Assessment   Commission 

(1900),  10:  35-60  passim 
Parish  and  Town  Officers  Act  (1793), 

10:  2n 
property,  statutory  valuation  of, 

10:  7-9 
property    taxpayer,    relief    for, 

10:  82-7 

Municipal  Tax  Assistance  Act, 

10:  85 

Municipal    Unconditional    Grants 

Act,  10:  86-7 


Property  tax,  real: 
history  —  Continued 

reform  measures,  10:  14-23 
Select  Committee  on  the  Municipal 
Act    and    Related    Acts    (Beckett 
Committee),   10:  89-90 
Select  Committees  of  the  Legislature, 

1909,  1912;  1918-19,  10:62-8 
single  tax  flirtation,   10:  61-70 
special-franchise  properties, 
10:  47-52 

Commission  on  Railway  Taxation, 
10:51-2 

and   Maclennan   Commission   re- 
commendations, 10:48,  50-51 
Supplementary  Business  Assess- 
ments, 10:  88-9 

the  Beckett  Committee,  10:  89 
twentieth-century   developments, 
10:  61-95 
importance    to    municipalities,    4: 42; 

6:  22;  8:  25;  10:  1,  77,  124-8 
incidence  of  increase: 

business  properties,  9:  34-7 
owner-occupied  residential  property, 

9:  31-3 
rented  residential  property,  9:  26-30 
loss   from  exemptions,  25   per  cent, 

10:99 
more  regressive  if  made  income  tax- 
deductible,  26:  179 
and  municipal  debt,  10:  119 
municipalities,  tax  differentials  within, 

11:  209-18 
payments-in-lieu,  10:  99,  100,  103 
the  present  position,  10:  96-128 
point  of  diminishing  revenue,  9:  42-4 
projected  increase,  8:  43 
provincial    equalization    factor   should 

be  subject  to  appeal,  11:  55-9 
realty  tax,  levying  of,  10:  112-20 
reduction  of  regressiveness,  8:  10,   15, 

18,  25 
relative   weights   on    various    property 

classification,  11:  208 
residential,  11:  69-118 

increased  weight  of,  11:  69-70 
Umitsof,  11:  120-22 
recreational  properties,  11:  123-30 
reducing  weight  of: 

basic    shelter   exemption, 
11:  100-119 

deductible   from   taxable   income, 
11:  87 
home-improvement  exemption, 

11:  89-94 
home-owner  grants,  11:  83-6 
partial  exemption,  11:  95-9 
progressive  rates,  11:88 
split  mill  rate,  11:  78-82 


328 


Property  tax,  real: 

residential  —  Continued 
statutory  tax  limit,  11:  71 
tax  reductions  for  selected  categories 
of  taxpayers,  11:  72-7 
school  board  reliance  on,  8:  10-11 
and  school  finance,  20:  72-87 

school  tax  dilTerentials,  20:  73-4 
split  mill  rate,  abolition  of,  21:  97 
suggested    billing    timetable,    regional, 

local,  school  taxes,  23:  168 
unpopular  but  invulnerable,  9:  1-2,  62, 

66 
variable  rate,  6:  2,  24-5 
see  also  Business  taxes 
Province  of  Ontario  Savings  Office,  36:  4 

Provinces: 

administration  of  justice,  assignment  of 

responsibility  for,  9:  91 
corporate  tax,  allocation  rules,  27:  82-3 
fiscal  policy,  use  of,  3:  9 
municipal  taxation,  the  base  of,  11:  3 

Provincial  debt: 

counter-cyclical  fluctuations,  objective 

of,  40:  11-12 
cyclical  fluctuations  in,  40:  11-13 
effect  of  recommendations,  1966,  8:  8 
expansion  of: 

fiscal  effects  of,  40:  8-9 

periods  of  most  rapid,  4:  59 
gravity  of  situation,  8:  46 
increase  since  1939,  4:  56 
increasing  level,  40:  5,  9 
net  direct  capital  debt,  4:  58,  59 
policy  to  1975,  40:  1-14 
present  burden  of,  4:60 
projected,   before    and   after   tax    rate 

changes,  8:  38,  39 
projected: 

burden  of,  40:  3 

effect  of  recommendations,  8:  31-43 
passim 
ratio  to  P.D.P.,  8:  13-22 
ratios,  4:  57 
see  also  Provincial-local  debt 

Provincial  Domestic  Product  (P.D.P.): 
definition,  6:  14 
projection,  6:  8,  14-20  8:  27-9 
Provincial  expenditures;  4:  22-41 

benefits,    net,    gained   by   residents   of 

Ontario,  5:  42-3 
benefit    rates — by    income   classes, 

5:  34-7 
cost  implications  of  possible  changes  in 

education   system,    6:  91-7 
gross  and  net,  4:  24-6 


Index 

Provincial  expenditures  —  Continued 
divergence  between,  4:  25,  26 
gross  less  grants  to  municipalities  and 
school    boards,    trends    in,    4:  30 
in  national  perspective,  4:  38-41 
net: 

by  function,  4:  34-5 
rate  of  change,  4:  27 
related  to  the  estimated  P.D.P.,  4:  31 
net  real,  4:  28 
net  real  per  capita,  4:  29 
patterns  summarized,  4:  32 
projections  of,  6:  56-112 

capital   expenditures,   other,   6:  108, 

109-11 
education,  6:  57-97 
health,  6:  101-6 
highways  and  roads,  6:  98-100 
including  provision  for  higher  school 

grants,  8:  31 
municipalities    and    school    boards, 

grants  to,  6:  112 
public  buildings,  construction  of, 
6:  107 
three  heaviest,  38:  1 

Provincial  government: 

authority  over  local  governments,  4:  20 

in  better  financial  position  than  munici- 
palities, 22:  86 

borrowing  capacity,  3:  36 

budgetary  and  debt  position,  projection 
of,  6:  113-19 

counter-cyclical  fiscal  policy,  feasibility 
of,  3:  29-42 

departmental    approval    of    municipal 
capital  borrowing,  22:  35 

executive  branch,  expansion  of,  4:  17- 
18 

expenditure-revenue  gap,  40:   1 
and  increased  taxes,  8:  46-8 
increasing,  8:  22 
projected,  6;   113-19 

federal  abatement  for  provincial  taxes, 
26:  111-18 

fiscal  effects  of  recommendations,  1966, 
8:  8-12 

fiscal  operations,  magnitude  of,  24:   1 

grants:  see  Grants,  provincial,  to  muni- 
cipalities 

income  taxes,  constitutional  aspects  of, 
26:  36 

miscellaneous  non-tax  revenues  of  de- 
partments, 37:  1 

need  for.  to  offset  parochialism,  9:   14 

net  fiscal  incidence,  pattern  of,  5:  46 

ownership  of  mineral  rights,  32:  6,  35, 
39;  34:  7 


Chapter  numbers  are  in  bold  face;  paragraph  numbers  in  light  face.    T=Table. 
Vol.  I,  1-8;  Vol.  II,  9-23;  Vol.  Ill,  24-40 


329 


Index 


Provincial  government:  — Continued 
patterns  of  expenditure,  revenue,  and 

debt,  4:  l-b6 
payments  in  lieu  of  local  taxes,  2:  110- 

11;  10:  85,  99,  100,  103;  12:  1,  3, 

9,  1 5,  20,  3  1 ,  35-44  passim,  68,  70 
payments  to  mining  municipalities:  see 

Mining    municipalities,    payments 

to 
projection  of  expenditure,  revenue  and 

debt    (1966-74)  —  basic    assump- 
tions, 6:  2-7 
property  tax  exemptions,  12:  30-72 
responsibility  for  promoting  economic 

stabilization,  2:  27-8 
responsibility     for     local     government 

organization,  2:   100-108 
school  boundaries,  2:  131 
should  have  right  to  appeal  any  or  all 

municipal  assessment,  11:  61,  62-5 
should  make  payments  in  lieu  of  taxes 

to  municipalities:  fiscal  effects,  8: 

6,  T8:  2 
should    take    over    administration    of 

justice,  9:  90-95 
fiscal  effects  for  local  governments, 

1966,  T8:   1;  8:  7n;  T8:  2 
implications  for  grants,  21:  91 
as  source  of  funds  for  health  services, 

38:  21,  23 
and  special  situations  of  municipal  bor- 
rowing, 22:   134-5 

Provincial  Land  Tax  Act,  13:  passim,  28: 

1;  33:  1 
appeal  procedure,  25:  27 
appointment  of  land  tax  collector,  13: 

39 
assessment,  basis  of,  13:  40 
exemption  of  places  of  worship,    12: 

119 
governing  assessment  of  real  property 

in  unorganized  territories,  13:  36, 

38 
and  property  tax  exemptions,  12:   12, 

13,  14 
revenue,    1965-66,   and   administrative 

body,  T25:   1 
transferring  the  assessment  provisions 

to  The  Assessment  Act,  13:  41-5 

Provincial-local  debt,  4:  56-65 
combined  revenue  gap,  40:  10 
compared  with  other  provinces,  40:  4 
historical  comparisons,  40:  4 
projection  to  1975,  40:  10 
ratios  of  burden,  4:  57 

Provincial-municipal  relations,  4:  20 
basic  principles,  2:  73 
combined  budgetary  and  debt  position, 
6:   120-23 


Provincial-municipal  relations: 
—  Continued 
combined    finances    as    percentage    of 

G.N. P.,  3:  21 
combined  real  net  revenue  as  propor- 
tion of  P.D.P.,  since  1939,  4:  54 
Committee's  philosophy  of,  2:  73-9 
contrasted  with  federalism,  2:  68 
equalization,  2:  76,  85 
expenditure    function,    division   of,    2: 

80-85 
fiscal  projection,  (1966-75),  6:  1-128 
increased     importance     of     combined 

finance,  3:  21-2 
local   autonomy,   2:    74,   80-83,    86-9, 

100 
mutual  taxation,  2:  109-13 
nature  of,  2:  67-72 
projection  of  expenditure,  revenue  and 

debt    (1966-74)  —  conclusion,    6: 

124-8 
property  tax,  2:  87-8 
provincial  assistance,  2:  77-8,  85,  90 
provincial  responsibility,  2:  75,  84,  86, 

100-101 
revenue    sources,    the    division    of,    2: 

86-90 
structural  complexity,  2:  71-2 
superior-subordinate  relationship,  2:  69 

Provincial  revenue,  4:  42-55 
alternative  sources: 
lotteries,  39:  2,  24-39 
transportation  tax,  39:  2,  3-23 
expenditure-based,    principal    compon- 
ents, 4:  47 
four  major  sources  of,  as  percentage  of 

P.D.P.,  6:  49 
gross,  since  1939,  4:  43 
major  classes,  percentage  breakdown, 

4:  46 
miscellaneous  sources,  37:  1-22 
net,  rate  of  increase,  4:  45 
net  ordinary,  as  percentage  of  P.D.P., 

6:55 
Ontario  Hospital  Services  Commission. 

as  source  of.  4:  50 
projected   effect  of  recommendations, 

1968-75,  8:  31 
projections  of,  6:  47-55 

federal  estate  tax,  share  of,  6:  50, 

T6:  7 
gasoline  tax,  6:  51,  T6:  7 
income  tax,  personal,  6:  53,  T6:  7 
motor  vehicle  licences  and  permits, 

6:  52,  T6:  7 
other  current  revenue,  6:  54-5 
policy  issues  arising  from,  40:  1-5 
reporting  of,  24:  5-6 
succession  duty  as  source  of,  declining, 
28:  59 


330 


Provincial  Revenue,  Department  of, 

recommendation  for  establishing, 
25:  7 

Provincial  revenue  system,  introduction, 
24:   1-15 

Provincial-school  board  relations: 

expenditure    responsibilities,    the   divi- 
sion of,  2:  116-18 

fiscal  implications,  2:  114-31 

local  autonomy,  2:  116-18,  122-3,  128 

principles,  2:  1 14-15 

provincial  responsibility,  2:  116-18,  122, 
125 
.for  viability  of  school  units,  2:   131 

revenue   sources,    the    division   of,    2: 
119-23 

separate  schools,  2:  115 

see  also  School  Finance 

Provincial  Secretary: 

fee  revenue,  37:  4,  T37:  1 

Public  Accounts  (provincial),  24:  5,  6 
criticism,  24:  7-13 

municipal  assistance,  treatment  of,  9: 
103 

Public  borrowing: 

"burden"  defined,  3:  46 
future-generations  theory,  3:  44-8,  50 
"pay-as-you-go"  view,  3:  49-50 
philosophies  of,  3:  43-54 

Public  Commercial  Vehicles  Act: 

administration  of  permits  and  licences, 

30:  34 
classes  of  P.C.V.  licences,  30:  49 
licence  fees,  30:  51 
number  of  vehicles  under  one  licence, 

30:  50 
provisions  of,  30:  46 

Public  employees — numbers,   growth  in, 
4:  19 

Public    health,    research    and    training, 
financing  of,  38:  45-56 

Public  Health  Act,  21:  68;  38:  7 

Public    Lands    Investigation    Committee, 
on  acreage  tax,  32:  149 

Public  Library  Act:  regional  library  sys- 
tem, 23:   HI 

Public  Schools  Act,  13:  37,  38 
assessors,  appointment  of,  13:  39 
property  tax  exemption,  12:  15 

Public  Utilities  Act,  11:  215 

capital  levies  (special) — initiating  works 
financed  by,  15:  4,  32 


Index 

Public  Vehicles  Act: 

administration  of  permits  and  licences, 

30:  34 
exemptions,  30:  47 
licence  fees,  30:  52 

Public  works:  see  Capital  levies,  special 

Public  Works,  Department  of,  revenue 
from  sales  and  rentals,  37:  13,  17, 
T37:  1 

Quance  v  Ivey,  18:  2 

Quebec: 

administration  of  justice,  responsibility 

for,  9:  91 
alcoholism  rates,  1939-61,  35:  71 
amusements  tax,  31:  22 
community  of  property,  28:  81 
corporate  income  tax,  27:  2 

rate,  26:  155 
federal  hospital  operating  grants,  com- 
pared with  per-capital  income,  38: 
37 
and  federal  "opting  out"  formula,  26: 

63,  74 
fire  insurance,  no  extra  tax  on,  31:  73 
fiscal  year  end,  municipalities,  14:  21 
and  foreign  tax  credit,  26:  164,  165 
forest  revenue: 

Crown  dues,  33:  12 
logging  tax,  33:  40 
tenure  charges,  33:  10,  11 
income  tax,  personal: 

abatement  rates,  1965-68,  26:  74 
adoption  of,  26:  3 

collection    agreement    with    federal 
government,  26:  51 
and  local  sales  tax,  19:  24-6,  31,  32 
meals  and  hotels  tax,  19:  6;  29:  54 
Meals  Tax  Act,  19:  6 
mineral  production,  value,  1966,  T32: 

5 
mining  acreage  tax,  T32:  9,  32:   144, 

151 
mining  profits  tax,  rates  of,  compared 

with  Ontario,  32:  124,  126 
mining  tax: 

base,  32:  25-31  passim 

rates  and  basic  exemption,  32:  32. 

33 
type  of,  32:  24 
motor  vehicle  fuel,  tax  rate  on,  30:  7 
motor  vehicle  registration  fees  (1964) 

T30:  4 
municipal   revenue   derived  from   per- 
mits and  licences,  17:  7 


Chapter  numbers  are  in  bold  face;  paragraph  numbers  in  light  face.    T=Table. 
Vol.  I,  1-8;  Vol.  IT,  9-23;  Vol.  Ill,  24-40 


331 


Index 


Quebec:  — Continued 

1962  income  tax  rates  (personal  and 

corporate),  26:  72 
personal  property  tax,  10:  38 
poll  tax,  use  of,  T16:  1;  16:  5 
power  exported  to  Ontario,  34:  19 
race  tracks  tax,  rate,  31:  44-5 
retail  sales  tax,  29:  14 

interprovincial  transactions  and  im- 
ports, 29:  118,  120 
rate,  29:  98 
sales  tax — production  machinery,  29: 

67 
Royal  Commission  on  Taxation  (Bel- 
anger  Commission): 
advertising  sales  tax,  29:  69 
corporate    taxes,    recommendations, 

27:  3 
instalment  tax  billing,  14:  41 
local  sales  taxes,  19:  31 
race  tracks  tax,  proposed  rate,  31: 

45 
and  reassessment  procedure,  13:  130 
on  state  of  assessing,  13:  27,  116 
on  uniform  succession  duty  statutes, 
28:  226 
should  tax  business  income  of  non-resi- 
dents, 26:  151 
school  board  fiscal  year,  14:  21 
succession  duties,  28:  40 
assessment  of,  28:  224 
compared  with  British  Columbia  and 

Ontario,  28:   155 
federal  cash  payment,  1964,  26:  75 
introduction  of,  28:  48,  49 
tax  rates  on  business  income,  26:  147-8 
tax  rental   agreements,    1947,   Quebec 

not  in.  26:  53 
tax-sharing  agreement  of  1957,  26:  62 
tobacco  tax,  31:  5,  7,  13 
toll  roads,  30:  74 

water  power  rentals,  34:  16,  17,  21 
Quebec  City: 

business  tax,  10:  38 
fiscal  year,  14:  21 
Quick  succession,  28:  116-17 

Race  track  companies;   corporate  taxes, 

27:  8 
Race  tracks  tax,  31:  33-47 

agency-collected,  25:  10 

conclusion,  31:  46-7 

description,  31:  33-5 

incidence  and  justification,  31:    38-40 

rates,  31:   34-5,  41-5 

revenue.    1965-66,   and   administrative 
body,  T25:  1 

yield.  31:  36-7 
Race  Tracks  Tax  Act: 

no  provision  for  appeal,  25:  27 


Railway  Fire  Charge  Act,  33:  6 
Railways: 

corporate  taxes,  27:  8,  9,  128,  133 
special  assessment  for,  13:  60-62 
vacant  lands  classification,  10:  30,  57 
valuation  of  property,  10:  19 
problem  of,  10:  48-51,  57,   107 
Re  Guardian  Realty  and  Toronto,  18:  5n 
Re  Ontario  Motor  League  and  Toronto, 

18:  5n 
Recommendations,  7 
Recommendations,  fiscal  effects  of,  8:  1- 
54 
concluding  comments,  8:  44-54 
direct  measurable  impact  on  provincial 

and  local  finance,  8:  2,  44 
fiscal  scene  in  1966-67  (hypothetical), 
8:  4-25 
local  governments,  8:  4-7 
local    government,    with    increased 

provincial  school  grants,  8:  23-4 
problem  of  debt  ratio,  8:  13-22 
provincial  governments,  1966,  8:  8- 
9,   12-14 
projection,   1968-75,  8:  26-43 
Recreation     and     community     services, 

grants  for,  21:  81-9 
Redevelopment  and  housing  grants,  21: 

75-80 
Reform  Institutions,  Department  of:  rev- 
enue from  sales,  37:  13,  T37:  1 
Regional  government,  suggested  scheme, 
23:  46-171 
and   Community   Enrichment   Grants, 

21:   88 
contract  municipalities,  23:  27-33 
equalized    taxable    assessment,    23: 
128 
county  regions,  23:  74-120 
criteria: 

balance  of  interests,  23:  41,  60 
community,  23:  40,  60 
efficiency,  23:  43-4,  60 
financial  adequacy,  23:  42,  60 
flowing  from  access  and  service,  23: 

39-45 
interregional    co-operation,    23:    45, 

60 
reviewing  the  criteria,  23:  58-61 
facilitate  co-ordination  of  health  units, 

38:  56 
financial  role  of  regional  government, 
23:   134-45 
assessment,  23:  135-6 
borrowing,  23:  143-5 
non-property  revenue,  23:   138-42 
income  tax,  personal,  23:   140-42 
motor  vehicle  tax,  23:  138-9 
tax  collection,  23:  137 


332 


Regional  government,  suggested  scheme 
—  Continued 

functions  performed  by  regions,  23:  57 
and  health  unit  grants,  21:  74 
implementation,  23:    148-54 
instalment  tax  billing,  14:  44 
justification  for,  23:  58-156 
metropolitan  regions,  23:  62-9 
and  municipal  borrowing,  22:  127 
northern  Ontario,  23:  52-6,  121-6 
district  regions,  23:  54,  121-6 
community   and  balance  criteria, 

23:   126 
taxable  assessment,  23:   122-3 
"metropolitan   regions,   23:    53,    121, 
124 
operational  functions,  23:   124-5 
relationship  to  economic  regions,   23: 

146-7 
southern  Ontario,  23:  47-51 
classes  of  regions  23:  47 
county  regions,  23:  50 
metropolitan  regions,  23:  48 
urbanizing  regions,  23:  49 
geographical  features,  23:  51 
and  welfare,  21:  52 
urbanizing  regions,  23:  70-73 

Regions,  county,  in  suggested  scheme  of 
regional   government,   23:   74-120 
balance  criterion,  23:  75 
community  criterion,  problem  of,  23: 

74 
financial  criterion,  23:  76-9 
functional  responsibilities,  23:  80 

allocation  of,  23:  81-2 
operational  functions,  allocation  of,  23: 
83-120 
arterial  roads,  23:  84 
concluding  points,  23:   117-20 
conservation,  23:  99-100 
co-ordination  of  protection  services, 

23:  101-3 
garbage  disposal,  23:   116 
hospital  facilities  planning,  23:    104 
library  services,  23:  110-12 
public  health,  23:  85 
public  welfare,  23:  86-90 

and  the  Advisory  Committee  on 
Child    Welfare    Report,     1964, 
23:  90 
categories  of,  23:  86 
transferring   local    jurisdiction    to 
regional  governments,  23:  87 
regional   parks   and    recreation,   23: 

98 
regional  planning,  23:  105-9 


Index 

Regions,  county,  in  suggested  scheme  of 
regional  government, 
operational  functions,  allocation  of 
—  Continued 

and  1964  amendment  to  The  Sec- 
ondary Schools  and  Boards  of 
Education  Acts,  23:  93 
water   supply   and   sewage   disposal, 
23:    113-15 

Regions,  district,  23:  54,   121-6 

Regions,  economic  (Ontario  Bureau  of 
Statistics  and  Research),  and  re- 
gional government,  23:  146-7 

Regions,  metropolitan,  in  suggested 
scheme  of  regional  government: 

differences  from  remaining  regions,  23: 
66-9 

disruption  of  existing  county  boundar- 
ies, 23:  64-5 

functions  discharged,  23:  66-7 

need  for,  in  regional  scheme,  23:  62-9 

segregation  of,  23:  62-3 

Regions,  urbanizing,  in  suggested  scheme 
of  regional  government,  23:  70-73 

"Registrants",  under  Motor  Vehicle  Fuel 
Tax  Act,  30:  14 

Remaindermen: 

deferred  payment  of  duty,  28:  178 

duties  payable,  effect  of  capital  pay- 
ments to  life  tenant,  28:  201 

interests  of,  and  succession  duties,  28: 
83-94,   112 

payment  of  duties,  28:  187 

Research  Foundation  Act,  property  tax 
exemption,  12:  16 

Residential  and  Farm  School  Tax  Assist- 
ance Grant,  20:  19,  73 

Resource  allocation: 

effects  of  changes  in  property  tax,  9: 
40-41 

effects  of  corporate  income  tax,  27:  58 

effect  of  income  tax,  26:  35 

and  local  autonomy  and  fiscal  responsi- 
bility, 9:  5-7,   19 

Retail  sales  tax,  29:  1-127 

administrative  considerations,  29:   100- 
121 
organization  of  staff,  29:  100-105 
advantage  over  selective  excise  taxes, 

1:  57 
agency-collected,  25:  10 
argument  in  support  of,  29:  2 
audits  and  tax  recoveries,  29:  104-5 


Chapter  numbers  are  in  bold  face;  paragraph  numbers  in  light  face.    T=Table. 
Vol.  I.  1-8;  Vol.  II,  9-23;  Vol.  Ill,  24-40 


333 


Index 


Retail  sales  tax  —  Continued 

breadth  of  tax  base  as  factor  in  inci- 
dence, 29:  22 
burden: 

borne  by  consumer,  29:  31 
distribution    among    taxpayers,    29: 

32-7 
factors  relating  to  incidence,  29:  22 
commissions  of  real  estate  agents,  31: 

70 
commission    of    security    dealers    and 

brokers,  31:  61 
cost  of  administering,  29:  43 
and  income  tax  compared: 

ellect  on  economic  growth,  29:  45 
etiects  on  saving  and  consumption, 

29:  44 
effects  on  work  incentive,  29:  40 
relationship    to    business   cycle,   29: 
47-8 
economic  effects,  29:  24-30,  38-48 
business  cycle,   relationship   to,   29: 

47-8 
economic  growth,  effect  on,  29:  45 
trictional  effects,  29:  40-43 
inflation  and  deflation,  29:  46 
revenue  yield,  29:  39 
saving  and  consumption,  effects  on, 
29:  44 
and  equalization,  2:  28 
equity,  29:  36,  49-50 
exemptions,  29:  49-94 

administrative  simplicity,  29:  73-4 
children's  clothing,  29:  62,  64 
effect  of  removal  of,  29:  34-5 
equity,  29:  49-50 
food  exemption,  29:  53-60 
medicines  etc.,  29:  61 
producers'  goods,  29:  65-7 
pyramiding  and  double  application, 

avoidance  of,  29:  65-72 
reduction  of  regressiveness,  29:  51- 

64 
services.  29:  82-93 
social  good,  29:  75-81 

summary    of    recommendations    re- 
garding, 29:  94 
expenditure  taxes,  comparison  of,  29: 
4-10 
single-stage  sales  tax,  29:  9-10 
turnover  tax,  29:  4-6,  42 
value-added  tax,  29:  7-8,  42 
fair  value,  determination  of,  29:  110 
gasoline  and  dicsel  fuel,  exemption,  30: 

16-21 
general  analysis  of,  29:  21-48 
gifts,  29:  116 
government  enterprises  liable   for,  36: 

20 
history  in  Canada,  29:  11-18 
and  the  hospitals  tax.  31:  32 


Retail  sales  tax  —  Continued 
incidence,  29:  21-31 
and  income  tax,  compared: 

effect  on  economic  growth,  29:  45 
effects  on  saving  and  consumption, 

29:  44 
relationship    to    business   cycle,    29: 
47-8 
insurance  premiums,  31:  80-83 
increase  in,  8:  14,  16,  18 
interprovincial    transactions    and    im- 
ports, 29:  117-20 
length  of  period  analysed  as  factor  in 

incidence,  29:  22 
local,  19:  22-34 

another  grant?  19:  30 
problems,  19:  28-9 
unrelated  to  needs,  19:  33 
monetary  and  fiscal  policies  as  factor 

in  incidence,  29:  22 
non-resident  contractors,  29:   113-14 
as  percentage  of  P.D.P.,  6:  49 
projected  increase,  8:  33,  34,  36,  37, 

39 
projected  revenue  from,  T6:  7 
rates,  29:  95-9 
differential,  29:  95 
progressive,  29:  96-7 
scope  for  change,  29:  98-9 
refund,  conditions  for,  25:  19 
removal  of  municipal  exemptions  rec- 

mended — fiscal  effects,  8:  5,  8 
rentals,  29:   115 
revenue,    1965-66,   and   administrative 

body,  T25:  1 
and  security  transfers,  31:  59-61 
as  source  of  provincial  revenue,  4:  46, 

47;  29:  19-20 
special    collection    arrangements,    29: 

111 
storage  of  goods,  29:  112 
summary  and  conclusions,  29:  121-6 
superiority  over  manufacturer's,  1:  61 
supply  and  demand  as  factor  in  inci- 
dence, 29:  22 
tax  base.  29:  49-94 

tobacco  products,  exemption  of,  31:  2 
on  transient  accommodation,  19:  10 
vendors: 

liability  of,  29:  109 
remuneration  to,  29:   106-8 
should  be  abolished,  35:  56 

Retail  Sales  Tax  Act,  1:  62;  29:  passim 

Revenue,  Department  of  (proposed):  and 
mining  taxes,  32:   134,  135 

Revenue,  government: 

projection,  1966-75,  6:   1-128 


334 


Index 


Revenue  legislation,  provincial,  adminis- 
tration and  appeals,  25:  1-41 
administrative    responsibility    for    rev- 
venue  raising,  25:  6 
agency-collected  taxes,  25:  10-11 
importance  of  audit,  25:  11 
licensing  of  agents,  25:  16-17 
appeal  procedure,  25:  27-39 

administrative  process  for,  25:  29-32 
Board  of  Review,  creation  of,  25: 

30-32 
costs  and  time  limits,  25:  36-9 
judicial  process,  25:  33-5 

need  for  specialization,  25:  35 
guidelines  for,  25:  34 
assessment  procedure,  25:  9-15 
"billing"  or  "self  assessing"  method, 

recommendations  for,  25:  12 
conclusions,  25:  40-41 
directly  collected  taxes,  25:  12 
information  memoranda,  publishing  of, 

25:  15 
liens,  25:  25-6 
penalties,  25:  22-4 

interest  rate,  25:  23 
refunds,  25:   18-21 
interest  rate,  25:  21 
recommendation,  25:  20 
responsibility    for    administration,    25: 
3-8 
Revenue    raising,    and    individual   rights, 

25:  6 
Revenue  statutes: 

appeal  procedure,  provisions  for,   25: 

27 
and  civil  rights,  25:  41 
essential    elements    in    administration, 

25:5 
fifteen  major  (1965-66),  25:  3,  T25:  1 
need  for  consistent  policy  in,  25:  40-41 
those  not  assigned  to  Treasury  Board, 
recommendation  for,  25:  8 

Richman,  Peggy  Brewer;  see  Musgrave, 
Richard  A. 

Rinfret,   C.   J.,    in   Sun   Life   v.    City   of 
Montreal,  11:  44n 

Roach,  Hon.  Mr.,  38:  58n,  60,  61 

Road  grants,   from  Province  to  munici- 
palities, 21:  9-35 

Rodd,  Stephen,  11:  192 

Royal  Agricultural  Winter  Fair,  exempt 
from  Hospitals  Tax  Act,  31:  15 

Royal    Commission    on    Banking    and 
Finance,  3:  43 
on  securities  market,  22:  147 


Royal  Commission  on  Dominion-Provin- 
cial Relations  (Rowell  Sirois  Com- 
mission), 2:  22;  26:  3n 

on  federal-provincial  responsibilities, 
2:  14 

on  regional  inequalities  of  income,  2:  7 

Royal  Commission  on  Health  Services 
(Hall  Commission),  38:  2 

on  federal  grants  for  public  health, 
research  and  training,  38:  47,  48 

and  federal  operating  grants,  38:  36, 
40 

health  service  structure,  38:  24 

merging  of  federal  hospital  construc- 
tion grants,  38:  29 

and  out-patient  services,  expenditure 
on,  38:41 

regional  planning,  38:  56 

on  regional  planning  and  co-ordination 
of  hospital  facilities,  23:  104 

Royal    Commission    on    Metropolitan 
Toronto: 
on    creation    of    a    smaller    "Metro", 

23:72 
and  road  grants,  21:  21 
Royal  Commission  on  Taxation  (Carter 

Commission),  27:  79,  99 
Royal  Ontario  Nickel  Commission,   32: 
88,  89 
on  mining  acreage  tax,  32:  147,   148, 
150 

Royalties: 

fishing  and  trapping,  34:  26-7 
on  natural  gas  wells,  34:  8,  9 
on  mines,  distinguished  from  tax,  32: 
38 

Ryerson,  Egerton,  10:  16 

Saint  John,  New  Brunswick,  turnover 
tax,  11:  145-6 

St.  John  Ambulance  Association,  prop- 
erty  tax  exemption,   12:  105 

St.    Lawrence    Parks    Commission    Act, 
property  tax  exemption,  12:  16 
revenue  from  sales,  37:  14 
St.  Marie  v.  St.  Marie,  12:  130n 

Sales  and  rentals,  provincial  departmental 
revenues  from,  37:  13-18,  T37:  1 

Sales  tax: 

retail:  see  Retail  sales  tax 
single-stage,  29:  9-10 
specific — unjustifiable,  19:  34 

Sanatoria,  tuberculosis,  conversion  to 
general  use.  38:  33,  40 


Chapter  numbers  are  in  bold  face:  paragraph  numbers  in  light  face.    T= 
Vol.  I,  1-8;  Vol.  II,  9-23;  Vol.  Ill,  24-40 


Table. 


335 


Index 


Sanatoria  for  Consumptives  Act,  property 
tax  exemption,  12:  15 

Sanders,  Thomas  H.,  Effects  of  Taxation 
on  Executives,  26:  13 

Saskatchewan: 

administration  of  justice,  responsibility 

for,  9:  91 
amusements  tax,  31:  22 
business  tax,  mandatory  levy  of  uni- 
form appHcation,  11:  147 
corporate  income  tax,  27:  2 
federal  hospital  operating  grants,  com- 
pared   with    per-capita    income, 
38:  37 
forest  revenue: 

Crown  dues,  33:  12 
tenure  charges,  1964,  33:  10,  11 
home-owner  grants,  11:  83 
income  tax,  personal: 
adoption,  26:  3,  48 
difficulties  of  higher  provincial  rates, 

26:  145,   146 
1962  rates,  26:  72 
interprovincial  movements  of  persons, 

26: 138 
mineral  production,  value,  1966,  T32:  5 
mining   lands   taxes,   T32:  9;    32:  144, 

145 
mining  tax: 

base,  32:  25-31  passim 
rates  and  basic  exemption,  32:  32,  33 
type  of,  32:  24 
motor  vehicle  fuel,  tax  rate  on,  30:  7 
motor  vehicle  licensing  reciprocity  with 

Ontario,  30:  60 
motor  vehicle  registration  fees,   1964, 

T30:4 
municipal   revenue  derived   from  per- 
mits and  licences,  17:  7 
poll  tax,  use  of,  16:  3,  5 
retail  sales  tax,  29:  13 
revenue  from  municipal  utilities,  17:  50 
revenue    from    public   enterprises,   36: 

1,  5 
Royal  Commission  on  Taxation: 
on  publicly  owned  utility,  36:  10 
and  reassessment  procedure,  13:  130 
state  of  assessing,  13:27,  116 
sales  tax  —  production  machinery,  29: 

67 
succession  duty,  adoption  of,  28:  48 
surtax,  reduction  of,  26:  155 
tobacco  tax,  T31:  1 

welfare:    introduction    of    mothers' 
allowances,   21:  37 

School  boards: 

allocation  of  federal  grants-in-lieu,  12: 
77,  85 


School  boards: — Continued 

allocation   of   provincial   payments-in- 

lieu,  12:  44-7 
allocation  of  spending,  20:  4,  5 
capital  borrowing  through  O.E.C.A.C., 

22: 136 
continuation  schools,  20:  9 
debt: 

increase  since  1939,  4:  56 
post-war  trends,  4:  61-5 
ratios,  4:  57 
elementary  —  grants,  20:  15 
expenditure: 

gross,  trends  in,  4:  30 
net: 

rate  of  change,  4:  27 
real,  4:  28 

real  per  capita,  4:  29 
projection,  6:  28-30 
function  of,  20:  3 

grants  from  Province:  see  Grants,  pro- 
vincial, to  local  governments 
independent  or  dependent?  20:  77 
licence  rates  for  commercial  vehicles, 

30:41 
and  mining  profits  tax,  12:  175,  176 
and  municipal  assessment,  20:  12,   13, 

14 
numbers,   public   and   separate,    1966, 

20:  8 
and  overlapping  municipal  boundaries, 

13: 138 
peculiar  functions,  2:  116-17 
peculiar  position,  2:  114 
relations  with  Province,  2:  114-31 
reliance  on  property  tax,  8:  10-11 
requisitioning,  problem  of,  2:  123 
revenue: 
gross: 

breakdown  of,  4:  52 
since  1939,  4:43 
net,  rate  of  increase,  4:  45 
secondary  —  grants,  20:  16,   17 
separate: 

borrowing,  22:  110 
capital,  22:  28 

should   be    through    municipality, 
22:  144 
corporation    tax    adjustment    grant, 
20:  28-30 

improving    the    structure    of,    20: 
52-9 
see    also    Local    government;    School 
finance 

School  boundaries,  and  the  Province,  2: 
131 

School  districts,  high,  in  two  or  more 
municipalities,  assessment  problem 
of,  13:  138 


336 


Index 


School  finance,  20:  1-87 
cost  control,  20:  85 
equity,  20:  86 

financing  minimum  standards,  20:  4 
functional  sharing,  20:  3 
local  autonomy,  20:  84 
Ontario    Foundation    Tax    Plan,    20: 

22-59 
Ontario  school  system: 

continuation    schools,    decline    of, 

20:9 
distinguishing  features,  20:  1-9 
district   high    school   boards,   multi- 
plication of,  20:  9 
.elementary  schools,  20:  8 
organization  of,  20:  8-9 
secondary  schools,  20:  9 
and  the  property  tax,  20:  72-87 

requisitioning   of   school   taxes,    20: 

75-9 
the  role  of,  20:  80-81 
provincial    grants,    historical    develop- 
ment, 20:  10-21 
contribution  to   school  finance,  20: 

20-21 
equalization,  20:  12-19  passim 
shifts  in  the  level  and  proportion  of, 

20:21 
see  also  Grants,  provincial,  to  local 
governments 
separate   schools,   constitutional   status 

of,  20:  6-7 
special    status   of   school   expenditure, 

20:5 
stimulation  grants.  20:  60-66 

incorporated  in  Foundation  Tax  Plan 
or  abolished,  20:  63-6 
vocational  education  grants,  20:  67-71 
see  also  Ontario  Foundation  Tax  Plan 

School  tax  assistance  grant,  11:  80 

Schools,  and  retail  sales  tax  exemptions, 
29:  76,  78 

Schools  Administration  Act,  property  tax 
exemptions,  12:  15 

Schools,  private,  property  tax  exemption, 
12:  113-14,  118 

Scott,  A.  D.,  on  grants  in  federal  coun- 
tries, 2:  49n. 

Secondary  Schools  and  Boards  of  Educa- 
tion Act,  20:  9 
amendment  to,  1964,  23:  93 

Security  transfer  tax,  31:  48-61 
agency-collected,  25:  10 
description,  31:  48-54 
exemptions,  31:  50 


Security  transfer  tax  —  Continued 
incidence,  31:  55-6 
justification,  31:  57 
rates,  31:  48 
revenue,    1965-66,   and   administrative 

body,  T25:  1 
yield,  31:54 

Security  Transfer  Tax  Act:  no  provision 
for  appeal,  25:  27 

Select  Committee  of  the  Legislature, 
1903:  alternative  to  personal  prop- 
erty tax,  10:  41,  44-6 

Select  Committee  on  Mining,  1966: 
on  acreage  tax,  32:  150,  152 
on  Crown  leases,  32:  155,  156 

Select  Committee  on  The  Municipal  Act 
and  Related  Acts  (Beckett  Com- 
mittee), 10:  89,  90,  101;  23:  57, 
146 

on  change  of  fiscal  year,  14:  20 

and  delineation  of  suitable  regional 
boundaries,  23:  64-5 

on  direct  election  of  representatives  at 
all  levels  of  government,  23:  150 

and  flat-rate  business  tax,  11:  153-4 

on  the  method  of  municipal  finance, 
10:96 

recommendations  on  regional  govern- 
ment, 23:  13-14 

and  tax  arrears  certificate  registration, 
14:82 

Select  Committee  on  Taxation  and  Ex- 
emptions (1878),   10:  31-2 

Separate  Schools: 

constitutional  status  of,  20:  6-7 

Tiny  Separate  School  Trustees  v.   The 

King,  20:  7n 
see  also  School  boards 

Separate  Schools  Act  of  1863,  2:  14;  13: 
37,  38;  20:  7 
assessors,  appointment  of,  13:  39 

Service  fees: 

provincial  government  departments,  37: 
4-12,  T37:  1 

Services,  proposal  to  include  in  retail 
sales  tax,  29:  82-93 

Sheppard,  D.  H.,  Federal-Provincial  Tax 
Collection  Arrangements,  26:  17 In 

Sheridan  Park  Corporation,  36:  4 
Shoup,  Carl,  28:  12 
Shoup  Mission,  28:  12 


Chapter  numbers  are  in  bold  face;  paragraph  numbers  in  light  face.    T^ 
Vol.  I,  1-8;  Vol.  II,  9-23;  Vol.  Ill,  24-40 


= Table. 


337 


Index 


Simons,  Henry  C,  Personal  Income  Taxa- 
tion, 26:  8n 

Single  Tax  Association,  10:  64 

Site-value  taxation,  10:  70;  11:  8-15 

Situs,  law  of: 

conflict  between  federal  and  provincial, 

28:67-71 
and  Ontario  succession  duties  on  non- 

Ontarians,  28:  209 
and  succession  duties,  28:  65,  67 

Sleeping,  parlour  and  dining  car  com- 
panies, corporation  taxes,  27:  8, 
131,  133 

Smith,  Adam,  1:  26,  60 

Smith,  Russell  D.,  on  The  Northern  Rail- 
way: Its  Origins  and  Construction, 
39:  28n 

Social  policy,  and  tax  principles,  1:  67-72 

Solicitor-client  privilege  and  Corporations 
Tax  Act,  27:  142 

Special  Committee  on  Corporation  Taxa- 
tion, 26: 186 

Spouses: 

as   business   partners,   present   income 

tax  treatment,  26:  181 
proposed    income    tax   treatment,    26: 
181-3 
Star  Transfer  Ltd.,  36:  4 

Statute  Labour  Act: 

authorization  of  poll  tax,  16:  1 
property  tax  exemption,  12:  16 

Stock  Yards  Act,  property  tax  exemption, 
12:  16 

Students'  supplies: 

sales  tax  exemption,   29:  80 

Succession  Duties  Act  (Canada),  tax 
credit  for  Ontario  duties,  26:  57 

Succession  duty,  28:  1 

administrative  considerations,  28:  170- 

209 
"aggregate  value",  calculation  of,  28: 

52-3,  119 
annuities,  small,  exemption  of,  28:  130 
annuities  and  pensions: 

duties  by  instalments,  28:  97 
valuation  of,  28:  96 
assessment,  28:  199-205 
appeals,  28:  204 

notice  should  be  issued,  28:  199-200, 
203,  204 
assets  held  in  safety  deposit  box,  28: 

180-84 
beneficiaries,  classes  of,  28:  56,  129 


Succession  duty  —  Continued 
calculation  of  tax,  28:  118-51 
aggregate  value,  28:  119 
dutiable  value,  28:  120 
charitable    donations    and    bequests, 
anomaly  produced  by,  28:  124-6 
community  of  property,  28:  81-2 
consent  to  transfer,  28:  185-6 
constitutional   limitations,    and   The 

Estate  Tax  Act,  28:  67 
deductions,    exemptions,    and    calcula- 
tion of  tax,  28:  118-51 
charitable   donations   and    bequests, 

28:  124-7 
expenses  of  estate,  28:  122-3 
family  and  dependants,  treatment  of, 
28:  128-51 

classes  of  beneficiaries,   28:  129 
dependant's  allowance,  28:  131 
dependant's   reduction,  28:  132 
preferential    tax    treatment    pro- 
posed, 28:  133-46 
small  annuities,  28:  130 
gift  tax,  28:  151 

liabilities  of  the  deceased,  28:  121 
description  of  present  Act,  28:  51-7 
dispositions: 

and  gift  tax,  28:  107,  109 
valuation  of,  28:  1 10 
"dutiable  value",  28:  52,  120 
duties  paid  from  residue  of  estate,  28: 

202 
vs.  estate  taxes,  28:  40-46 
and  the  BNA  Act,  28:  44 
difference  between,  28:  40-41 
even  small  estates  should  be  taxable, 

28:  149-50 
exemptions,  28:  54 
family  businesses,  preservation  of,  28: 

189-96 
family    and    dependants,    proposed 
preferential  tax  treatment  of,  28: 
134-46 
calculation  of  duty,  28:  147 
children,  28:  139-41 
children  infirm  of  body  or  mind,  28: 

142 
grandchildren,   28:  144 
orphan  child,  under  25,  28:    143 
parents  claim  to  insured  portion  of 
exemption  of  dependent  children, 
28:  145 
widow,  28:  137-8 
federal  cash  payment,  1964,  26:  75 
federal  government  should  vacate  field, 

8:  50 
foreign  estates,  28:  206-9 
gift  tax,  exemptions  proposed,  28:  151 
importance  of  complementary  gift  tax, 
28:  214 


338 


Succession  duty  —  Continued 
information  returns,  28:  170 
interest  in  expectancy,  28:  92-4 

settling  of  duties,  28:  93-4 
joint  property,  28:  74-80 
life  interests  and  interests  of  remainder- 
men, 28:  83-94 
deferred  payment  of  duties,  28:  85, 

86-7 
duty  by  instalments,  28:  85,  88-90 
lump-sum  payment  of  duties,  28:  91 
method  of  payment,  28:  177-8 
no  rate  increases  proposed,  8:  18 
payment  of  duties,  28:  171-9 
as  percentage  of  P.D.P.,  6:  49 
postponement    of    payment,    28:  179, 

195-6 
preferential   treatment   of  dependants, 

justification  of,  28:  134 
the  present  Ontario  duty,  28:  47-57 

history,  28:  47-50 
private  woodlots,  28:  197-8 
projected  adjustment  (1971-72),  8:  36, 

37 
projected  revenue  from,  T6:  7 
property  passing  on  death,  28:  72-3 
rate  of  tax,  28:  152-6 

Ontario  structure,  28:  152-4 
compared  with  Quebec  and  British 
Columbia,  28:  155 
rate  structure,  proposed,  28:  157-69 
compared   with   Canada   rates,    and 

Ontario-Canada  rates,  28:  167 
effect  of,  28:  167-8 
lowest  rate,  28:  160 
marginal  rates,  28:  158 
maximum  rate,  28:  161 
proportional   or   progressive?   28: 

157-8 
schedule  of  basic  rates,   28:  162-6 
recommended  increases,  8:  49 
relief  from  burdensome  duties,  28:  179 
revenue,    1965-66,   and   administrative 

body,  T25:  1 
security  for  duty,  28:  187-8 
small    bequests    and    dispositions,    28: 

148 
as  source  of  revenue,  28:  58-60 
tax  base  for,  28:  61-117 

agreements  for  sale  and  purchase, 

28:  104 
annuities  and  pensions,  28:  95-7 
and  the  BNA  Act,  28:  61 
conflict    between    federal    and    pro- 
vincial bases,  28:  67-71 


Index 

Succession  duty, 

tax  base  for  —  Continued 
constitutional  limitations 
law  of  situs,  28:  65 
law  of  domicile,  28:  63 
dispositions,    28:  105-10 
employers  of  the  deceased,  payments 

from,  28:  98-9 
life  insurance,  28:  100-102 
property  passing  for  partial  or  full 

consideration,  28:  103 
quick  succession,  28:  116-17 
standard  of  value,  28:  111 
summary  of,  28:  66 
valuation  date,  28:  112-15 
Succession  Duty  Act  (Ontario): 
appeal  procedure,  25:  27 
need  for  rewriting,  28:  51,  57 
Sun  Life  v.   City  of  Montreal,    11:  44n, 

50n 
Supplementary   Revenue  Act,   1899,  27: 

6,  9 
Supplementary  Revenue  Act,  1907,  32:  3 

mines  profits  tax,  10:  71 
Sweden,  annual  wealth  tax,  28:  9 
Switzerland,  capital  gains,  26:  193 

Tax  abatements,  federal,  to  provinces,  26: 

66-74,   111-18 
additional    required,    8:49,    51-4;    26: 

155 
alternatives,  8:  53 
for  health  service  programs,  38:  24,  29, 

30,  35,  42 
higher  for  Quebec  —  implications  for 

foreign  tax  credit,  26:  165 
and  provincial  tax  rates,  27:  91 
rates,  1962-66,  26:  158 

Tax  credits,  interprovincial: 

advantage  over  present  allocation  sys- 
tem,   26:  147-9 
disadvantages,  26:  150-52 
Tax  sale  arrangements,  14:  74-8 

termination  proposed  by  Beckett  Com- 
mittee, 10:  90;  14:82 
Taxation: 

ad  valorem  tax,  defined,  25:  10 

and  constitutional  democracy,   1:  3-20 

and  economic  policy,  1:  16-20 
departures  from  benefit  and  ability-to- 
pay  principles,  9:  54-5 
direct,  defined,  25:  9 
direct  and  indirect,  distinction  between, 

30:  28 
equity  in,  1:  20-50 


Chapter  numbers  are  in  bold  face;  paragraph  numbers  in  light  face.    T= Table. 
Vol.  I,  1-8;  Vol.  II,  9-23;  Vol.  Ill,  24-40 


339 


Index 


Taxation:  —  Continued 
and  fees,  1:  27 
of  government  entities,  2:  60-66,   109- 

13 
government  finance,   the   Committee's 
piiilosophy  of,   1:  1-72 
constitutional  democracy  and  society, 

1:  12-15 
constitutionalism    and    individual 

rights,  1:  7-11 
democracy  and  the  "common  good" 
defined,  1:  5-6 
incidence: 

assumptions  regarding,  5:  App. 

by  family  money-income  class,  1961, 

T5:2 
forward-shifted    taxes,    percentage 
borne  by  Ontario  residents,  5:  14 
method  of  estimating,  5:  9-17 
as  percentage  of  adjusted  broad  in- 
come, T5:  6 
"progressive"  and  "regressive"  rates 

defined,  5:  30 
shifting  to  non-residents,  5:  11,  13-15 
on  income,  consumption  or  wealth,  1: 

36-9 
joint  occupancy  of  tax  fields,  2:  32-40 
maintenance  of  balance  in  face  of  in- 
creases, 8:  47-8 
as  a  major  component  of  government 

fiscal  operation,  3:  5 
as   means   of   attaining   economic   ob- 
jectives, 1:  18 
progressivity,   and  law  of  diminishing 

marginal  utility,  1:  41-7 
rates  of  tax  by  income  classes  (Ontario), 

5:  30-31,  33 
specific  tax,  defined,  25:  10 
tax  system,  principles  of: 
adequacy,  1:  52 
balance,  1:  55-6 
certainty,  1:  60-62 
conflicts  of,  1:  66 
convenience,   1:  64 
economy    of    collection    and    com- 
pliance,  1:  65 
elasticity,  1:  54 
equity,  1:  21-50 
flexibility,  1:  53 
neutrality,   1:  57-9 
simplicity,  1:  63 
and  social  policy,  1:  67-72 
see  also  Revenue  legislation,  provincial; 
Revenue    statutes;    and    specific 
taxes 

Tax  Reform  League,  and  single  tax  flirta- 
tion, 10:  64 

Tax  Structure  Committee,  26:  76-7 


Technical  and  Vocational  Training  Assis- 
tance Act,  1960,  20:  67 

Technical  Training  Program,  federal 
abatement  for,  26:  114,  115 

Telegraph  and  telephone  companies:  cor- 
porate taxes,  27:  8,  9,  129,  133 
gross  receipts  or  mileage  tax  proposed, 

10:51 
special  assessment  for,  13:  47-9 

Telegraph  and  telephone  services,  retail 
sales  tax  on,  29:  82 

Telephone  Act;  capital  levies  (special), 
initiating  works  financed  by,  15:  4, 
30-31 

Thompson,  Lawrence  E.,  see  Butters,  J. 
Keith 

Tile  Drainage  Act:  capital  levies  (special), 
initiating  works  financed  by,  15:  4, 
27-9 

Tiny    Separate    School    Trustees    v.    the 
King,  20:  7n 

Tobacco  tax,  31:  2-13 
agency-collected,  25:  10 
comparison  with  other  provinces  and 

states,  31:  5-7 
conclusion,  31:  13 
description,  31:  2-4 
federal  tax  increases,   1951-53,  31:  6 
incidence,  31:  8-9 
justification,  31:  10-12 
projected  increase,  (1971-72),  8:  36,  37 
or  retail  sales  tax,  29:  81 
revenue,    1965-66,    and   administrative 

body,  T25:  1 
and  smuggling,  31:  6 
social  policy,  1:  67,  68 
yield,  expected,  1967-68,  31:  2 

Tobacco  Tax  Act,  31:  4 

Tocqueville,  Alexis  de,  on  municipal  in- 
stitutions, 23:  25 

Toronto,  City  of: 

income  tax  assessment,  26:  46,  47 
partial,  graded  exemption  of  dwelling 
units,  10:  67,  70;  11:  95,  97;  12:  4 
personal  property  tax,  10:  39 
tax  exemption  of  improvements,  10:  65 

Toronto,  Metropolitan,  Municipality  of: 
capital   items   financed   from   revenue, 

22:  100 
and  the  Community  Enrichment  Grant, 

21:  89 
debentures,  22:  142-3 
debentures    for    subway    bought    by 

Province,  22:  134 


340 


Index 


Toronto,  Metropolitan,  Municipality  of: 
—  Continued 
an  experiment,  23:  11 
grant-making  power,  12:  138 
local  income  tax,  estimated  yield,  19: 

18 
pooled  borrowing  operations,  23:  144, 

145 
as  prototype  of  regional  government, 

23:  11-12,  151,  154 
road  grants  to,  21:  16,  17,  21 
three-year    council    term,    and    capital 

debt,  22:  89,  102 

Toronto    General    Burying    Grounds    v 
■   Scarborough,  12:  130n 

Toronto  Stock  Exchange,  as  collector  of 
security  transfer  tax,  31:  53 

Toronto  Transit  Commission,  17:  35 

Tourism    and    Information,    Department 
of:  museum  grants,  21:  82 

Touzel,  Bessie,  on  welfare  services  in  Peel 
County,  23:  16n 

Transfer  fees: 

liquor  licence,  35:  50-52 
motor  vehicle,  30:  57,  59 

Transfer  payments: 

complicate  reporting  of  government 
finance,  4:  23 

distinguished  from  government  expen- 
diture on  goods  and  services,  5:  19 

federal,  to  Ontario,  4:  49 

Transport,  Department  of: 

as  collector  of  motor  vehicle  permit 

and  licence  revenues,  32:  132 
revenue    from    permits,    licences,    fees 

and  fines,  30:  34 
Vehicle  Inspection  Branch,  30:  53n 

Transportation,    estimated    spending   on, 
Ontario,  1963,  39:  8 

Transportation   and   communications 
properties: 
business  tax  on,  11:  165-74 
case  for  exemption,  11:  171-2 
special  assessment  for,  13:  50-53 
valuation,  problem  of,  11:  167-8,   173 

Transportation  tax: 

an  alternative  source  of  provincial 

revenue,  39:  2,  3-23 
conclusions,  39:  21-3 
constitutional  considerations,  39:  17-20 
description,  39:  3-7 
economic  considerations,  39:  15-16 


Transportation  tax. —  Continued 
history  of,  in  Canada,  39:  4-5 
in  other  countries,  39:  6-7 
potential  yield,  39:  8-10 
shifting  and  incidence,  39:  11-14 
freight  and  express  charges,  39:  14 
passenger   travel,  39:  12-13 

Treasury  Department,  proposed  Board  of 
Review  within,  25:  30 

Trees  Act,  12:  15,  150,  152 

Trust  companies,  corporate  taxes  on, 
27:8 

Turnover  tax,  29:  4-6 
criticism  of,  29:  5 
defined,  29:  4 

Unemployment:  government  programs, 
21:  40-43 

Unemployment  assistance,  federal  abate- 
ment for,  26:  114,  115 

Unemployment  Assistance  Act,  21:  42 

Union  of  Ontario  Municipalities,  and 
single  tax  flirtation,  10:  65 

United  Kingdom: 

assessment  of  farm  property,  13:  20 
and  capital  gains,  26:  191,    193,   194, 

197 
death  taxes,  28:  47 
differential  tax  treatment  by  class  of 

taxpayer,  9:  70 
electricity   and   gas  boards  subject  to 

income  tax,  36:  21 
farm  properties: 

assessment  of,  13:  20 
taxation  of,  11:  178 
Local  Government  Act  (1958),  21:  101 
Report  of  the  Committee  of  Inquiry 

into    the    Impact    of    Rates    on 

Households,     on    instalment    tax 

billing,  14:  41n 
Royal  Commission  on  Local  Taxation, 

9:90 
Royal  Commission  on  the  Taxation  of 

Profits  and  Income,  26:  11;  27:  73 
schools  dependent  on  municipal  coun- 
cil, 20:  77 
and  single-stage  sales  tax,  29:  9 
study  of  price  and  income  elasticity  of 

demand  for  liquor,  35:  77-81 

passim 
implications  for  Ontario,  35:  82-3 
succession  duty: 

basic  exemption,  28:  133 


Chapter  numbers  are  in  bold  face;  paragraph  numbers  in  light  face.    T= 
Vol.  I,  1-8;  Vol.  11,  9-23;  Vol.  Ill,  24-40 


:  Table. 


341 


Index 


United  Kingdom: 

succession  duty: — Continued 
maximum  rate  of  tax,  28:  161 
private  woodlot,   death  tax  on, 

28:  198 
rate  of  tax,  compared  with  Canada 

and  U.S.,  28:  156 
ruhngs  on  property  passing  on  death, 
28:72 
valuation  of  property,  13:  117 

United  States: 
Advisory  Commission  on  Inter-Govern- 
mental Relations,  13:  135 
and  assessment,  13:  8 
on  local  non-property  taxes,  11:  143 
assessment: 

farm  property,  13:  20 

at  a  specified  percentage  of  value, 

11:67 
state  operation  of  function,  13:  117 
and  betting  at  Ontario  tracks,  31:  42 
capital  gains,  26:  192,  193,  197,  199 
Commission    on    Money    and    Credit, 

26:  16 
concentration  of  Canadian  trade  with, 
and  corporate  income  tax  levels, 
27:66 
corporate  financing,  27:  61 
death  taxes,  adoption  of,  28:  47 
differential  tax  treatment  by  class  of 

taxpayer,  9:  70 
estimated   yield   of   pool    on   sporting 

events,  39:  37 
hotel  and  motel  rooms  tax,  19:  5,  7 
land  transfer  tax,  31:  62 
liquor  stores: 

government    and    private,    revenue 

compared,  35:  62 
private,  summary  financial  statement, 
35:60 
local  income  taxes,  19:  13,  17 
local  sales  taxes,  19:  22,  23,  34 
lotteries  in,  39:  27 
motor  vehicle  revenues,  in  relation  to 

road  costs,  30:  4n 
municipal  licensing  of  motor  vehicles, 

30:80 
municipal  taxation,  base  for,  11:  3 
property  tax  differentials,  and  the  loca- 
tion of  business  and  people,  9:  45 
referendum,  extensive  use  of,  22:  124 
retail  sales  tax  exemptions,  29:  50 
and  single-stage  sales  tax,  29:  9 
study  of  price  and  income  elasticity  of 
demand  for  liquor,  35:  79-81 
implications  for  Ontario,  35:  82-3 


United  States:  — Continued 
succession  duty: 

basic  exemption  and  deductions, 

28:  133 
dispositions,  three-year  period  prior 

to  death,  28:  107 
rate  of  tax,  compared  with  UK  and 

Canada,  28:  156 
valuation  date,  28:  115 
toll  roads,  30:  74 
transportation  tax  in,  39:  6,  7 

Universities   and   colleges,    property    tax 
exemption,  12:  108-12,  118 

University  Affairs,   Department  of, 
12:  109,   110,   112 
no  incidental  revenue,  37:  2 
Student  Aid  Branch,  36:  7 

University  of  Toronto: 

debt  guaranteed  by  Province,  36:  22 
loans  from  Province,  36:  8 

User  fees  and  charges,  municipal: 
description,  17:  25-7 
justifiable  level  of,  17:  28-30 
summary  of,  17:  30 

Utilities: 

municipal,  special   assessment  for, 
13:  65-8 

private   enterprises  with   special   fran- 
chises, 10:  47 

special  assessment  for,  13:  50-53 

valuation  of  property,  problem  of, 
10:48-51 

Utility  companies: 

corporate  income  tax,  27:  28 
corporate  tax  transferred  to  provinces, 
27:  103-4 

Value-added  tax: 
criticism  of,  29:  8 
defined,  29:  7 

Veterans  Housing  Act,  1945,  property  tax 
exemption,  12:  16 

Vineberg,  Solomon,  10:  37n,  39n 
on  business  assessment,  10:  46 
Provincial  and  Local  Taxation  in  Can- 
ada, 26:  41  n 

Walker,  Mabel,  on  lotteries,  39:  26n 
Wartime  Housing  Act,  property  tax  ex- 
emption, 12:  16 
Water  power  rentals,  34:  12-24 

agreements,  34:  13-14 

average  revenue  per  kw.h.,  34:  21 

conclusion,  34:  24 

economic  considerations,  34:  18-23 

systems  of  other  provinces,  34:  16-17 


342 


Index 


Wealth,  taxation  of,  1:  37-9 

Wealth  tax: 

accessions  tax,  28:  12-17 

annual  net  wealth  tax,  28:  6-10 

death  taxes,  28:  18-23 

gift  tax,  28:  1 1 

justification,  28:  2-4 

opposition  to,  28:  4 

as  source  of  provincial  revenue,  4:  46 

types  of,  28:  6-23 

see  also  Property  tax;  Succession  duty 

Welfare: 

grants  from  Province  to  municipality, 

■    21:  36-61 
local   administration,    problem   of, 
21:  47-52 

Welfare    measures,    and    drop    in    self- 
employment,   4:  10 

Wells,   H.    G.,   on   administrative   areas, 
23:31 

West  Germany: 

exports  and  direct  (corporate)  tax,  27: 

63 
transportation  tax,  39:  6 
wealth  tax,  annual,  28:  9 

White,  Sir  Thomas,  on  personal  and  cor- 
porate income  tax,  26:  4 

Windsor:   personal   property   tax,    10:  39 

Wine: 

Ontario    prices   compared    with    other 

provinces,  35:  35 
special  position   of  Ontario   wines, 

35:35 
tax  on  Canadian,  35:  38 

Wineries,  fees  for,  35:  37 


Wineries'  own  retail  stores: 

percentage  of  total  sales  of  alcoholic 

beverages,  35:  29 
sales  and  control  of  alcoholic  beverages 
— off-premises    consumption, 
35:  13,  19 
Winnipeg:  personal  property  tax  replaced 

by  business  tax,  10:  38 

Winter  works  projects,  municipal:  grants 

from  senior  levels  of  government, 

21:90 

Withholding  taxes,  non-resident,  27:  106 

provinces  barred  from  imposing  during 

term  of  fiscal  agreement,  26:  85 
provinces  should  share  in  yield,  8:  50; 
26:  129-30 
Woodlots,  private,  and  succession  duties, 

28:  197-8 
Workmen's  Compensation  Act,  38:  59 
assessment  procedure,  38:  59-61 
investment  securities,   38:  62 
medical  and  hospital  care  facilities, 

38:  57-62 
missing   from   Public  Accounts,   24:  8 
health   services,  financial  support   for, 
38:  19 

Young  Men's  Christian  Association,  prop- 
erty tax  exemption,  12:  17,  105 

Young  Women's  Christian  Association, 
property  tax  exemption,  12:  17, 
105 

Youth  Allowances  Act,  federal  tax  abate- 
ment for,  26:  113 

Yukon: 

mineral  production,  value,  1966,  T32: 

5 
no  federal  tax  abatement,  26:  116 


Chapter  numbers  are  in  bold  face;  paragraph  numbers  in  light  face.    T=Table. 
Vol.  I,  1-8;  Vol.  II,  9-23;  Vol.  Ill,  24-40 


343 


164133 


Dote  Due 

DEC  5 

1976 

^,  -m 

"MAY  '^A 

W78 

M/|V> 

0"'  O 
4    N/h 

^  y^f  Ti 

nrTi  I 

lf979 

OCT  1  9 

1979 

NOV  1 1 

1979 

%\fyM  1  0  -1^ 

Tfl 

FORM  109 

I