Skip to main content

Full text of "Short run cost functions for Class II railroads"

See other formats


UNIVERSITY  OF 

ILLINOIS  LIBRARY 

AT  URBANA-CHAMPAIGN 

BOOKSTACKS 


Digitized  by  the  Internet  Archive 

in  2011  with  funding  from 

University  of  Illinois  Urbana-Champaign 


http://www.archive.org/details/shortruncostfunc321char 


Faculty  Working  Papers 


SHORT  RUN  COST  FUNCTIONS  FOR  CLASS  II  RAILROADS 


Alberta  U.  Cliamsy,  llancy  D.  Tidhu 
and  John  F,  Due 

#321 

Transportation  Research  Paper  Wo.   12 


College  of  Commerce  and  Business  Administration 

University  of  Illinois  at  Urbana-Champaign 


FACULTY  WORKING  PAPERS 
College  of  Commerce  and  Business  Administration 
University  of  Illinois  at  Urbana-Champaign 

July  29,  1976 


SHORT  RUN  COST  FlWCTIOigS  FOR  CLASS  II  RAILROADS 


Alberta  H.  Cliamsy,  llancy  D.  fidhu 
and  John  F.  Due 

#321 
Transportation  Research  Paper  Uo.   12 


SHORT  RUN  COST  FUNCTIONS  FOR  CUSS  II  RAILROADS 
Alberta  H.  Charney,  Nancy  D.  Sldhu,  and  John  F.  IXie 

There  Is  a  substantial  mileage  of  light  traffic  railroad  lines  In  the 
United  States  and  yet  little  Is  known  of  the  cost  behavior  of  these  roads. 
Knowledge  of  their  cost  functions  is  necessary  to  determine  to  what  extent 
these  light  density  lines  can  be  made  more  economically  viable  by  a  traffic 
increase.  The  economic  viability  of  a  light  traffic  road  depends  to  a 
large  extent  upon  the  manner  in  which  costs  react  to  a  change  in  the 
volume  of  traffic.  If  total  costs  change  very  little  with  an  increase  in 
volume  (that  is,  marginal  cost  is  very  low),  then  improvement  of  traffic 
will  have  a  substantial  impact  upon  average  cost  and  therefore  upon 
profitability. 

This  paper  seeks  to  determine  the  short  run  responsiveness  of  various 
cost  categories  to  volume  changes.  Specifically,  this  paper  is  concerned 
with  the  short  run  cost  functions  of  a  sample  of  ten  Class  II  railroads 

for  the  period  1963-1973.  Other  work  has  previously  been  reported  on  the 

2 
long-run  cost  functions  for  this  group. 

The  first  part  of  this  paper  describes  the  statistical  work  used  to 

estimate  the  short  run  cost  functions  of  these  railroads  and  the  estimates 

of  the  average  costs  derived  therefrom.  Then,  elasticities  are  derived  to 


^Class  II  railroads  are  those  with  annual  gross  revenues  of  less  than 
$5  million. 

^Nancy  D.  Sldhu,  Alberta  H.  Charney,  and  John  F.  Due,  "Cost  Functions 
for  Class  II  Railroads,"  Faculty  Working  Papers.  No.  262,  College  of 
Commerce  and  Business  Administration,  University  of  Illinois  at  Urbana- 
Clifimpalgn,  1975. 


I  y^^r-  ' 


Indicate  the  magnitude  of  the  reductions  in  average  costs  that  result  from 
an  increase  in  traffic  density. 

I 

The  model.   Traditionally,  economists  divide  a  firm's  total  costs  in  the 
short  run  into  a  fixed  component  that  does  not  vary  with  changes  in  output  and 
a  variable  component  that  does.  This  classification  is,  however,  inadequate 
when  applied  to  railroads.  The  usual  examples  of  fixed  costs  do  exist  in 
railroading:  depreciation  of  equipment,  interest  charges,  some  taxes  (e.g., 
property  taxes),  some  minimal  administrative  costs  (necessary  to  hold  the  firm 
together),  and  a  normal  rate  of  return  on  capital.  However,  the  variable 
cost  component  requires  disaggregation  Into  three  groups.  The  first,  or 
constant  variable  costs,  are  costs  that  can  be  eliminated  if  the  railroad 
la  not  operating  (their  variable  dimension)  but  change  very  little  if  at  all 
when  railroad  output  changes  (their  constant  dimension).  A  major  item  in  this 
group  is  minimum  track  maintenance  cost.  The  second  group  of  variable  costs 
are  more  or  less  constant,  in  total,  per  train  and,  therefore,  vary  only 
with  incrementa  of  output  large  enough  to  require  operation  of  more  trains. 
For  example,  the  size  of  a  train  crew  does  not  vary  with  the  number  of  cars 
but  the  man-hours  vary  with  the  number  of  trains  operated  per  time  period. 
The  third  group  of  variable  costs  includes  the  usual  variety  that  vary 
directly  with  the  level  of  traffic.  These  include  part  of  the  fuel  costs, 
any  taxes  related  to  traffic  levels,  per  diem  charges  and  switching  costs. 
If  additional  traffic  comes  from  different  sidings. 

This  brief  classification  scheme  implies  that,  aside  from  the  fixed 
costs,  total  railroad  costs  can  be  expected  to  vary  with  volume  but  less 


-3- 


than  proportionately.  More  tonnage  requires  more  assembly  time,  etc., 
and  if  great  enough,  more  trains.  Because  some  costs  are  related  to  terminal 
operations,  Independent  o£  the  length  of  haul.  It  would  also  be  expected 
that  increased  length  of  haul  would  not  increase  costs  proportionately. 

Let  us,  therefore,  begin  with  a  function  determining  total  costs  (TC): 

(1)  TC  ■  f  (tons,  average  length  of  haul) 
Dividing  both  sides  by  the  unit  of  output  ton-miles  (T-M): 

(2)  AC  =  ^  -  f<ton8,  average  len;sth  of  ha^l)^ 
We  choose  a  linear  specification  of  (2)  to  get: 


(3)   AC  «  a  +  bi  average  length  of  haul  ^  u     tons 
1         X-M  2  x-M 


-  a  +  bi  i  +  b,  i  , 
^  V     -^  D 

ti^ere  V  ■  volume,  or  ton-miles  divided  by  average  length  of 

haul,  and 

D  -  distance,  or  ton-miles  divided  by  total  tons. 

Equation  (3)  represents  one  of  the  functional  forms  used  in  estimation  of 

short  run  statistical  average  cost  functions  in  this  paper. 

The  use  of  equation  (3)  assumes  that  average  costs  approach  an  asymptote, 

a,  as  V  and  D  increase.  To  avoid  this  restriction,  we  also  ran  each 

regression  presented  in  this  paper  in  a  semi- log  form: 

(3*)   AC  »  a  +  b  InV  +  b^lnD. 

Results  of  these  regressions  are  summarized  below.   It  will  become  evident 

that  differences  between  the  two  models  are  not  great  over  the  observed 

ranges  of  output. 


It  was  expected  that  the  signs  of  b  and  b.  would  be  positive  for  the 
inverse  model  and  negative  for  the  semi-log  models  indicating  that  average 
costs  per  ton-mile  decline  as  volume  or  distance  or  both  increase. 

Ihe  data.  Data  for  this  study  were  compiled  from  annual  reports  filed 
by  ten  railroads  (listed  on  Table  1)  with  the  Interstate  Commerce  Commission 
for  the  years  1963  through  1973.   We  collected  data  and  calculated  figures 
fox  total  tons,  ton-miles,  average  length  of  haul,  and  the  eighteen  cost 
items  that  are  listed  in  Table  2  for  each  year  for  each  of  the  ten  roads. 

To  avoid  biasing  the  results  on  account  of  inflation  during  the  sample 
time  period,  all  items  that  required  it  were  deflated.  We  tried  to  match 
the  index  used  as  a  deflator  as  closely  as  possible  to  the  variable  to  be 
deflated.  For  example,  all  cost  components  involving  wages  were  deflated 
by  an  index  of  "wages — excluding  supplements,"  train  fuel  by  an  index  of 
"fuel  costs,"  property  taxes  by  a  weighted  average  of  relevant  property  tax 
deflators.   Further  details  on  the  deflating  procedures  are  available 
from  the  authors  upon  request. 

Because  of  the  number  of  observations  on  each  road  is  relatively  small, 
we  had  hoped  to  pool  the  data  to  increase  the  efficiency  of  our  estimates. 


^Our  heartfelt  thanks  go  to  Mr.  Robert  Byrne,  formerly  with  the  Rail 
Services  Planning  Office,  I.C.C,  who  arranged  to  make  copies  of  the  annual 
reports  available  to  us. 

Association  of  American  Railroads,  Yearbook  of  Railroad  Facts.  1974 
edition,  was  the  source  of  the  wage,  fuel,  and  "other  materials  and  supplies" 
deflators.  Where  appropriate  we  also  used  as  deflators  the  wholesale  price 
index,  the  federal  unemployment  index,  and  the  federal  retirement  index, 
and  property  tax  indices  of  the  various  states  assessing  railroad  property 
belonging  to  roads  in  our  sample. 


TABLE  1 
RAILROADS  IK  THE  SAMPLE 


Line 

..,N9t 

Railroad  Name 

Abbr. 

Median  V 

Median  D 

1 

Arcade  &  Attica 

ASA 

17.193 

4.837 

2 

Amador 

AMAD 

102.253 

11.790 

3 

Apache 

APAC 

515.560 

43.258 

4 

Bellefonte  Central 

BELC 

59.303 

5.611 

5 

Cadiz 

CAD 

27.147 

10.000 

6 

City  of  Prlnevllle 

CoP 

359.799 

18.340 

7 

Corinth  &  Counce 

C&C 

876.424 

10.000 

8 

Hlllsboro  &  Northeastern 

HNE 

19.160 

5.000 

9 

Mississippi  Export 

MISS 

795.121 

38.413 

10 

Pecos  Valley  Southern 

PVS 

48.736 

13.925 

*Distance  la  measured  In  miles;  volume  is  measured  in  thousands  of  tons. 


TABLE  2 
RAILROAD  COSTS  USED  AS  DEPENDENT  VARIABLES 

Type  of  Cost  Abbr, 

I.  Total  Operating  Costs  C 

A.  Maintenance  of  Way  Costs  C 

la 

1.  Roadway  maintenance  q. 

2,  Other  maintenance  of  way  coats  Ci 

B.  Maintenance  of  Equipment  Costs  0-.^ 

lb 

1,  Locomotive  repairs  Cii, 

2,  Equipment  depreciation  C,. 

Ib2 

3,  Other  maintenance  of  equipment  costs  Cii, 

C.  Transportation- Rail  Line  Costs  C, 


'Ic 


1.  Einployee  compensation    (of  train  crews)  C, 

Ici 

2.  Train  fuel  costs  C, 

^^2 

3.  Costs  of  loss,  damage,  casualties,  and 

personal  injuries  Ci 

4c  Other  transportation  coats  d 

lc4 

D.  Traffic,  Administrative,  and  Miscellaneous  Costs  C, ^ 

Id 

II.  Other  Expanses  E 

rtc 

A,  Equipment  Rentals  E 


c 


B.  Elate  of  return  calculated  on  railroad  equipment  E 

C.  Tax  Payments  E^ 
III.  Total  Railroad  Costs  (I  plus  II)                           ALL 


■5- 


Because  we  expected  correlations  to  exist  between  the  disturbances  of 
equations  for  different  railroads,  an  attempt  was  made  to  utilize  a  generalized 

least  squares  (GLS)  estimator  proposed  by  Zellner  for  situations  involving 

5 
what  he  calls  seemingly  unrelated  regressions.   This  estimator  also  has 

the  desirable  small  sample  properties  of  unbiasedness  and  efficiency 

6 
relative  to  the  ordinary  least  squares  (OLS)  estimator. 

However,  an  unexpected  computational  snag  developed  that  made  it 

impossible  to  use  the  GLS  procedure.  The  many  matrix  manipulations 

required  for  GLS  resulted  in  computer  roundoff  errors  which  were  large 

enough  to  result  in  slightly  negative  numbers  in  the  diagonal  of  the 

variance- cover lance  matrix- -an  impossibility.  Rather  than  push  the  data 

farther  than  it  could  legitimately  go,  we  therefore  are  presenting  here 

only  the  ordinary  least  squares  (OLS)  results  for  each  railroad.   Comparisons 

with  the  few  successful  GLS  runs  indicate  that  the  OLS  parameter  estimates 

are  substantially  the  same,  as  is  to  be  expected  because  the  OLS  and  GLS 

estimators  are  both  unbiased.   However,  the  OLS  standard  errors  are  larger, 

and  therefore  the  OLS  estimators  are  less  efficient. 


^The  original  article  is  A.  Zellner,  "An  Efficient  Method  of  Estimating 
Seemingly  Unrelated  Regressions  and  Tests  for  Aggregation  Bias."  Journal 
of  the  American  Statistical  Association,  LVII:  2  (June  1962),  pp.  348-368; 
or  see  the  discussion  in  Jan  Knenta,  Elements  of  Econometrics  (New  York: 
the  Macmillan  Company,  1971),  pp.  517-529. 

Small  sample  properties  of  these  estimators  are  worked  out  in 
A.  Zellner,  "Estimators  of  Seemingly  Unrelated  Regressions:   Some  Exact 
Finite  Sample  Results,"  Journal  of  the  American  Statistical  Association. 
LXIII:  4  (December  1968),  pp.  1180-1200. 


Three  rallroeds  in  our  9aniple--the  City  of  Prineville, 
Corinth  &  Counce,  and  Hillsboro  £e  Northeastern- -showed  little  or  no 
variation  in  their  distance  figures  ver  the  sample  yetrs;  so  we  had  to 
run  their  regressions  in  the  following  single  variate  form: 

(4)   AC  =  a  +  b  ij,  and 

(4')  AC  «  a  +  blnV. 

We  also  ran  the  other  seven  roads  using  equations  (4)  and  (4')  for  purposes 

of  comparison.  We  shall  indicate  where  the  differences  between  the  two 

versions  are  large. 
The  results. 
Examination  of  the  results  shows  that  the  overall  quality  of  the 

estimated  cost  functions  varied  widely.  The  best  results  of  the  group 

are  those  for  the  Mississippi  Export  and  the  Pecos  Valley  Southern,  and 

the  worst  are  for  the  Apache, 

In  the  single  variate  analysis,  most  of  the  volume  coefficients  have 

the  correct  sign.  Sign  reversals  tended  to  occur  mostly  in  the  smallest 

cost  components  like  C,,   rather  than  in  the  larger  divisions  like  C  ,  end 

Ibo  lb 

only  four  o^  these  ere  significant!'"  different  from  zero^     Model  II 
(equation  (4))  is  preferred  over  Model  I  (equation  (4'))  in  slightly  more 
than  ons-half  of  the  cost  equations.  This  preference  is  based  largely  on 
sign  reversals  and  significance  of  the  b  coefficients  and  the  values  of  F 
since  the  estimated  amount  of  Model  I  serial  correlation,  shown  by  the 
Durbin-Watson  statistic  in  the  last  column,  is  almost  always  close  to  that 
of  the  Model  II  version. 

The  equations  incorporating  both  volume  and  distance  show  the  following 
differences  from  the  single  variable: 


-7- 


(1)  Addition  of  the  distance  variable  tends  to  increase  slightly  the 
number  of  sign  reversals  of  the  volume  coefficient  bj^; 

(2)  At  the  same  time,  it  also  decreases  the  number  cf  significant 
volume  coefficients.  This  phenomenon  appears  more  or  less  at  random  except 
for  equipment  rentals  (E  );  here,  b,  was  reduced  to  insignificance  In  four 
of  the  seven  roads  we  compared,  and  we  can  conclude  that  the  blvariate 
specification  may  well  be  incorrect  in  this  case.  On  the  other  hand, 

(3)  Well  over  one-half  of  the  distance,  or  average  length  of  haul, 
coefficients,  the  b2S,  are  of  the  wrong  sign,  and 

(4)  Only  about  one-eighth  of  the  b^s  are  significantly  different  from 
zero.  The  significant  b.s  also  appeared  at  random,  though  about  one- third 
of  them  occurred  with  the  various  maintenance  of  way  costs.  This  finding 
leads  to  the  contrary  suspicion  that  for  a  few  cost  items,  the  blvariate 
specification  is  the  correct  one. 

Of  more  Interest  are  the  descriptive  uses  to  which  these  equations  can 
be  put.  We  calculated  the  average  cost  per  ton-mile  of  each  road,  for  a 
year  in  which  it  experienced  its  median  volume  level  and  median  average 
length  of  haul.  These  costs  are  displayed  in  Tables  3  and  4,  calculated 
from  the  tables  for  the  Individual  road.  Several  items  are  of  note: 

(1)  The  costs  estimated  in  Table  4  are  remarkably  close  to  those 
shown  in  Table  3  with  the  exception  of  the  Arcade  &  Attica,  for  which  the 
single  variate  model  estimates  average  total  costs  that  are  about  two  cents 
per  ton-mile  less  than  those  of  the  blvariate  model.  This  difference  is 
due  to  the  significant  distance  variable  for  Arcade  &  Attica.  As  expected, 
most  of  the  two  cents  difference  is  accounted  for  in  the  maintenance  of  way 


TAflLi;    3 


Estimated  iv.edian  Costs  per  Ton-Mile 
for  Sample  Railroads--'/olu;Tfie   Only  * 


Type  of 

(1)** 

(6) 

(8) 

(5) 

(3) 

(7) 

Cost 

I.iodel 

A&A 

AI-'IAD 

APAC 

B5LC 

CADIZ 

CoP 

1 

"1 

I 

$.^935 

$.0392 

$.0201 

:^.1494 

0.1786 

.;.o4i3 

2 

II 

.ii-652 

.0889 

.0200 

.  1479 

.1758 

.  0403 

3 

Clft 

I 

.1275 

.0^^2 

.  0034 

.0270 

.  0B26 

.0102 

u. 

II 

.1192 

.  Qkin 

.0063 

.0267 

.0840 

.0101 

5 

^la, 

I 

.0783 

.0420 

.  0066 

.0155 

.0732 

.0081 

6 

II 

.0725 

.0420 

.0065 

.0154 

.0750 

.0080 

7 

^la2 

I 

.Q492 

.0022 

.0018 

.0114 

.0095 

.0021 

8 

II 

.Oi^.V? 

.0022 

.0018 

.0113 

.0090 

.0021 

Q 

"lb 

I 

.0818 

.0115 

.0031 

.0211 

.0226 

.0065 

10 

II 

.0806 

.0112 

.0030 

.0207 

.0217 

.0064 

11 

n 
-Ibl 

I 

.0393 

.0051 

.0013 

.0035 

.0053 

.0049 

12 

II 

.0339 

.0050 

.0013 

.0034 

.0054 

.  0049 

13 

"lb2 

I 

.0099 

.  0038 

.0002 

.0116 

.0058 

.0010 

1^ 

II 

.0097 

.  0035 

.0002 

.0112 

.0058 

.0010 

15 

Ot.3 

I 

.0308 

.0024 

.0015 

.0060 

.0115 

.0005 

16 

II 

.0303 

.0024 

.0015 

.0060 

.0105 

.0005 

17 

Cl^ 

I 

.1685 

.0246 

.0067 

.0611 

.0549 

.0196 

18 

Ic 

II 

.1565 

.0246 

.0066 

.0609 

.0515 

.01^4 

19 

^le^ 

I 

.0993 

.0122 

.0023 

.0293 

.0252 

.0112 

20 

XCJ 

II 

.0916 

.0122 

.0028 

,0290 

.0238 

.0111 

21 

^ICg 

I 

.0110 

.0027 

.0010 

.0018 

.0056 

.0012 

22 

II 

.0102 

.0027 

.0010 

.0018 

.0057 

.0012 

2^^ 

Cl=3 

I 

.0092 

.0013 

.0012 

.0033 

.00004 

.0012 

II 

.  0089 

.0013 

.0012 

.0033 

.00003 

.0012 

25 

"Ic^ 

I 

.0/1.90 

.0085 

.0017 

.0267 

.0241 

.0060 

26 

II 

.  oi^SB 

.0034 

.0017 

.0268 

.0221 

.0059 

27 
28 

"Id 

I 

II 

.1157 
.1089 

.0039 
.0089 

.0020 
.0020 

.0403 
.0396 

,0184 
.0136 

.0050 
.0049 

29 

'2 

I 

.0212 

.0153 

.0051 

.0146 

.002? 

.0039 

30 

""r 

II 

.0130 

.0153 

.0050 

.0150 

.0024 

.0039 

51 

3_ 

I 

.0268 

.0053 

.0011 

.0091 

.0205 

.0043 

32 

c 

II 

.0252 

.0053 

.0011 

.0039 

.0191 

.  0043 

33 

"t 

I 

.0368 

.0081 

.0032 

.0175 

.0166 

.0023 

3i^ 

II 

.0353 

.0081 

.0032 

.0171 

.0157 

.0027 

35 

ALL 

I 

.5763 

.1184 

.0294 

.1905 

.2185 

.0523 

36 

II 

.5^24 

,1181 

.  0292 

.1888 

.2131 

.0518 

(continued  on 

the  next 

page ) 

Type  of 

(10) 

Cost 

iiodel 

I 

1 

,7.0220 

2 

II 

.0220 

Cla 

I 

.0066 

k 

II 

.0066 

I 

=la, 

I 
II 

.  oo^^3 
.00^3 

7 

Cla, 

I 

.  002'J- 

R 

li 

.002^!- 

9 

-lb 

I 

.0027 

10 

II 

.0023 

11 

=1^1 

I 

.0007 

12 

II 

.0007 

13 

^lb2 

I 

.0013 

14 

II 

.0013 

15 
16 

=»3 

I 
II 

.0008 
.0008 

17 

°lc 

I 

.0091 

J  o 

XNi* 

II 

.0090 

19 

=  10, 

I 

.0059 

20 

II 

.0058 

21 

■^ICo 

I 

.0007 

22 

2 

II 

.0007 

23 

°lc~. 

I 

.0009 

2i4- 

■^  J> 

II 

.  0009 

25 

^Ic/^ 

I 

.0016 

26 

II 

.0016 

2? 

^Id 

I 

.0036 

23 

X  -^ 

II 

.0035 

29 

■^ 

"r 

I 

.0075 

30 

II 

i007J^ 

31 

Sp 

I 

.0012 

32 

c 

II 

.0012 

33 

2t 

I 

.0037 

y^ 

II 

.0037 

35 

ALL 

I 

.03^5 

3'- 

II 

.0343 

TA3LS  3    CONTINUSD 


(2) 


mn. 


(9) 

i  iloS 


(4) 


J. 1689 

0.0217 

^.0386 

.1677 

.0212 

.0853 

.0^0^ 

.0067 

.0265 

.  Qklv7 

.0065 

.0253 

,0170 

.0049 

.0137 

.0131 

.0047 

.0129 

.026^!- 

,0019 

.0123 

.  0266 

.0018 

.0125 

.0123 

.0027 

.0105 

.0125 

.  0026 

.0100 

.0016 

.0010 

.0018 

.0017 

.0009 

.0018 

.0062 

.0009 

.0051 

.0055 

.0008 

.  0048 

.0051 

.0008 

.0033 

.0053 

.0008 

.0032 

.057^ 

.0100 

.  0344 

.0572 

.0098 

.0332 

.0089 

.0012 

.0165 

.0093 

.0011 

.0160 

.0005 

.0002 

.0006 

.0006 

.0002 

.0006 

.0004 

.0016 

.0032 

.0004 

.0016 

.0032 

.  0476 

.0070 

.0141 

.0470 

.0069 

.0135 

.0553 

.0022 

.0173 

.0533 

.0022 

.0167 

.0315 

.0075 

.0039 

.0312 

.0076 

.0037 

.0233 

.0009 

.0088 

.0267 

.0009 

.0086 

.0123 

.0022 

.0037 

.0124 

,0022 

.0084 

.2410 

.0323 

.1101 

.2379 

.0319 

.1061 

*The  median  costs  v;ere   estimated  using  each  road's  median  volume 
level   as  the  value  of  the   independent  variable   in  the   equations   of 
\ppendix  Tables   1   through   11. 


**The  numbers  above  the  columns  indicate  the  ordering  of  the  railroads  by 
median  volume. 


TABLE  4 


Estimated  Median  Costs  per  Ton-i-lile  for 
Saraple  Rp.ilroads- -Volume  and  Distance* 


1 
2 

3 
if. 

5 
6 

n 
I 

8 


Tyt)e  of 
Cost 


'1 
'la 


'la. 


'lag 


'lb 


'Ibi 
'Ibo 


lb. 


Hod  el 

I 

II 

I 
II 

I 
II 

I 
II 

I 
II 

I 
II 

I 
II 

I 
II 


'^Ic 

I 

II 

-ici 

I 
II 

-1=2 

I 
II 

=103 

I 
II 

;ic4 

I 
II 

I 

II 

^^r. 

I 
II 

c 

I 
II 

^^t 

I 
II 

ALL 

I 

II 


(1)** 

^>.5027 

.1366 
.1327 
.0860 
.0830 
.0^07 
.0498 

.0853 

.OB53 
.0^1-26 

.0i^25 
.0093 
.0093 

.0315 

.0317 

.1670 
.1578 
.0977 
.0917 
.0107 
.0101 
.00'33 
.  0086 
.  O^i-97 
.0^75 

.1133 
.1089 
.0230 

.0213 
.0265 
.025^^- 
.0384 
.0361 

.5887 
.5673 


(5) 

Am  AD 


(6) 


(4) 


.11^ 


B2I 


.0902 

0.0188 

.0889 

.0190 

.  0441 

.0077 

.0441 

.0078 

.0418 

.0060 

.0419 

.0060 

.0023 

.0017 

.0022 

.0017 

.0123 
.0113 

.0057 

.0050 
.0039 
.0038 
.0026 
.0025 

.0246 
.0246 
.0120 
.0122 
.  0026 

.0027 
.0014 
.0013 
.0037 
.0035 

.0091 
.0089 
.0149 

.0153 
.CO53 
.005s 
.0080 
.0081 

.1139 
.1131 


.  0029 
.0029 
.0013 
.0013 
.0002 
.  0002 
.0013 
.0014 

.0063 
.0064 
.0027 
.0027 
.0010 
.0010 
.0010 
.0011 

.0015 
.0016 

.0020 
.0020 

.0051 
.0050 
.0011 
.0010 

.0031 
.0031 

.0280 
.0282 


.;5.1493 

.1480 

.0269 

.0267 

.0155 
.0154 

.0114 
.0113 

.0211 
.0207 

.0035 
.0034 
.0116 
.0112 
.0060 
.0061 

.0611 
.0609 
.0293 
.0290 
.0013 
.0018 

.0033 
.0033 

.0267 
.0265 

.0403 
.0396 
.0146 
.0150 
.0091 
.0039 

.0175 
.0170 

.1905 
.1838 


(2) 

CAJia 

M787 
.175^ 
.0818 
.0833 
.0721 
.0741 
.0096 
.0091 

.0227 
.0217 
.0052 
.0052 
.0055 
.0055 
.0120 
.0110 

.0562 

.0524 

.0252 

.0235 

.0055 

.0056 

,00005 

.00004 

.0254 

.0232 

.0130 
.0181 
.0028 

.0025 
.0207 
.0190 
.0170 
.0160 

.2191 
.2129 


(7) 

$.0216 

.0211 
.0067 
.0064 
.  0048 
.0046 
.0019 
.0013 

.0027 
.0026 
.0010 
.0009 
.0009 
.0008 
.0008 
.0008 

.0100 

.0099 

.0012 
.0012 
.0002 
.0002 
.0016 
.0016 
.0070 
.0069 

.0022 
.0022 
.0074 

.0075 
.0009 
.0009 
.0022 
.0021 

.0321 
.0315 


(3) 


^.0900 
.0367 
.0272 
.0260 
.0145 
.0137 
.0127 
.0123 

.0104 
.0100 
.0018 
.0018 
.0052 
.0049 
.0033 
.  0032 

.034-'^ 

.f^.'35 
.0166 
.0162 
.0006 
.0006 
.0030 
.0030 
.0143 
.0137 

.0178 
.0172 
.00-17 
.0035 
.  0088 
.0086 
.0088 
.0085 

.1114 
.1074 


*The  median  costs  were   estiiaated  using  each  road's  median  levels   of 
volume  and  distance   as   the  values   of  the   independent  variables   in  the   equa- 
tions  of  Appendix  Tables   12   through  IS. 

**The  numbers  Above  the  columns  Indicate  the  ordering  of  the  railroads  by  median 
volume . 


-8- 


category,  Cj^^  (with  about  one  cent  due  to  different  estimates  of  roadway 
maintenance  (Cj^^^  )  alone),  and  most  of  the  rest  shows  up  in  equipment 
maintenance,  Cj^j^,  particularly  locomotive  repairs,  C,.  . 

(2)  If  the  roads  are  ordered  according  to  median  volxime  level,  and 
their  average  total  costs  are  compared,  the  expected  pattern  (AC  falls  as 
V  rises)  appears.  We  calculated  the  Spearman  rank  correlation  coefficient 
for  these  two  variables  and  found  it  to  be  significantly  different  from 
zero  even  at  the  .001  level.  This  relation  is  also  displayed  graphically 
in  Figures  3  and  4. 

(3)  If  the  ten  roads  are  again  ordered  by  median  volume,  a  tendency 
exists  for  the  ratio  of  average  operating  costs  to  average  total  costs 
(C^/ALL)  to  fall  as  median  volume  rises.  The  Spearman  rank  correlation 
coefficient  is  significant  at  the  .01  level  for  this  comparison.  However, 
no  one  component  of  operating  costs  displays  this  characteristic  to  any 
noticeable  degree. 

(4)  Opposite  tendencies  exist  for  the  ratios  of  average  returns  to 
capital  to  I  /erage  total  cost  (i^/A"*!)  and  for  average  rentals  to  average 
total  cost  (Ep/ALL).  The  rental-to-cost  ratio  tends  to  rise  as  median 
volume  rises,  while  the  return-to-cost  ratio  tends  to  fall. 

Another  method  of  displaying  these  results  is  graphical.  On  Figures  1 
and  2  we  have  plotted  the  average  total  cost  curves  for  all  ten  railroads 
in  the  sample.  The  lengths  of  the  curved  segments  indicate  the  range  of 
volume  observed  for  each  railroad  in  the  sample  time  period. 


'For  a  discussion  of  the  uses  and  calculation  of  this  statistic  and  for 
tables  of  significance  for  small  samples,  see  Sidney  Siegel,  Nonparametric 
Statistics  for  the  Behavioral  Sciences  (New  York:  McGraw-Hill  Book  Co., 
1956),  pp.  202-213,  284. 


o 


:-^ 


-4  >J 


M 
0) 
DU 

CO 
V 


o 

OB 
O 

o 
o 


P4 


o 
o 

CM 


\1' 


M  2 


w  i3 


0 

60  O 

to  t-4  H 
M    (0 

0>    4J  VI 

>    O  (U 

<   H  O. 


< 
I 


' __. >. 


I 

o 

in 


1 
o 


o 
o 


-  o 


tt  s 


O 

-o 
o 


!     I 


i     i     '     ' 


i..J:i 


i 

!    ■    i 

■ 

-- 

I 

■  1  ■ 

i 


-I i 

—  . 

1 

'" 

' 

1 

o 
o 

ON 


o 
o 
00 


o 
o 


o 
o 


o 

o 


o 
o 


u 

0) 

p. 

<a 

i-i 


CO 

o 
o 

o 


o 
o 

CO 


O     1 

00        p 

CO  -<  H 

w  a 

U    4J    M 

>    O    ffl 

1 

<  H    Ck. 

i 

.    o 

m 

o 
o 

«M 


o 
o 


_  o 


-9- 


These  curves  are  plotted  using  the  single  variate  models  of  equHtions 
(4)  and  (4*)  because  we  did  not  have  a  complete  set  of  equations  (3)  and 
(3')  for  all  ten  roads„   However,  the  role  of  distance  is  indirectly 
observable  in  the  following  way:  Take  any  volume  level  experienced  by  two 
or  more  railroads.   If  X  length  of  haul  has  any  effect  on  costs,  then  the 
road(s)  with  the  longer  median  length  of  haul  (from  Table  1)  should  exhibit 
lower  average  total  costs  per  ton-mile  on  Figures  1  and  2o   Indeed,  with 
but  a  few  possible  exceptions,  this  proves  to  be  the  case.  As  examples, 
consider  the  following:  The  Arcade  &  Attica  had  the  shortest  median  length 
of  haul  in  the  sample  and  the  highest  average  total  cost  curve;  the  Pecos  Valley 
Southern  had  a  longer  median  distance  and  a  lower  average  total  cost  curve  per 
ton-mile  than  did  the  Amador;  the  same  is  true  for  the  Apache  compared  with 
the  City  of  Prineville  or  the  Mississippi  Exports  The  only  exceptions  to 
this  general  relation  are  those  cases  where  the  average  total  cost  curves 
for  two  roads  intersect,  so  that  the  conclusions  to  be  drawn  about  X  average 
length  of  haul  cannot  be  clearcut, 

II 

For  each  cost  item  of  each  railroad,  the  elasticity  of  total  cost 

with  respect  to  ton-miles  was  calculated  at  the  median  volume  levels.  The 

8 
elasticities  were  derived  from  the  single  variable  equations  as  follows: 


For  several  reasons,  only  the  single  variate  models  were  used  for 
calculating  the  elasticities.  Not  only  was  the  distance  variable 
insignificant  for  many  cost  items,  but  it  also  caused  some  of  the  volume 
variables  to  change  signs.  Also,  for  some  of  the  ten  railroads  the  distance 
variable  could  not  be  used  because  there  was  little  or  no  variation  in  that 
variable. 


-10- 


For  the  semi- log  model  (using  equation  4'),  we  have  average  cost 

A .;  -  I£-  =  a=b  InV  =  a  +   InV 
T-M 

where  AC  =  average  cost 
TC  =  total  cost 
T-M  »  ton-miles 

M  =  miles  of  the  road. 
Then      TC  -  a  (T-M)  +  b(T-M)ln(T-M/M) 

MC  =  i-S£-  =  a  +  b  rin(T-M/M)  +  h\ 

d  T-M        L  ^     '   ^ 

=  a  +  b  ln(T-M/M)  +  b 
=  AC  +  b 
Therefore  for  Model  I, 

®TC  •  T-M  =  ^  ^^  •  ^••°' 
d  T-M   TC 

=  (AC  +  b)  «  i^ 
AC 

_  MC 

AC 

For  the  inverse  model  (using  equation  4),  we  have  average  cost: 

AC  =>  I^  =  a  +  b(l/V)  =  a  +  b  (M/T-M). 

T-M 

Then       TC  =  a  (T-M)  +  bM 

MC  =  i-^^  =  a. 
d  T-M 

Therefore  for  Itodel   II, 

®TC   •   T-M  «  i-I^  °  1^ 
d   T-M       TC 

=  a   •  IzH 
TC 

=  M£ 
AC  * 


-11- 


Note  that  the  elasticities  are  equal  to  marginal  cost/average  cost 
for  both  mod'^ls.  When  marginal  cost  is  very  small  compared  to  average  cost, 
an  Increase  in  the  traffic  on  that  road  should  substantially  reduce  average 
cost  and  therefore  substantially  improve  the  profitability  of  the  road. 
Therefore,  the  elasticities  measure  the  extent  to  which  roads  can  be  made 
more  economically  viable  by  a  traffic  increase. 

Table  5  contains  the  calculated  elasticities  for  each  railroad  and 
each  cost  category.  Observe  that: 

(1)  The  roads  are  ordered  with  respect  to  their  median  volume  levels 
to  see  if  the  elasticities  of  light  density  roads  are  different  from  the 
elasticities  of  the  heavy  density  roads.  Examination  of  the  elasticities 
indicates  that  the  elasticities  are  independent  of  the  volume  of  traffic 
of  the  road.  The  correlation  between  volume  and  the  elasticities  of  the 
"ALL"  variables  is  -.166  (almost  zero).  Low  elasticities  appear  for  bokj 
high  volume  roads  as  well  as  low  volume  roads. 

(2)  Some  of  the  elasticities  of  certain  cost  items  are  greater  than 
unity,  imply,  ig  that  as  volume  incre;  jes,  total  cost  increases  more  than 
proportionately.  This  occurred  most  frequently  for  the  maintenance  of  way 

costs  (C,  )  (including  both  subcategories  and  roadway  maintenance  (C^  ,  )» 

9 
"other"  maintenance  of  way  costs  (C^a-)),  and  costs  of  loss,  damage, 

casualties  and  personal  injuries (C.   ). 

(3)  Some  of  the  elasticities  are  negative.  For  model  II,  this  occilrs 
when  the  sign  of  the  coefficient  a  is  not  of  the  expected  sign.  Most  of 


This  effect  would  likely  vanish  if  a  period  of  years  was  used  instead 
of  a  single  year.  When  volume  Increases  noticeably,  roads  try  to  catch  up 
on  badly  deferred  maintenance. 


TABLE  5 
ELASTICITIES,  EACH  COST  CATEGORY,  EACH  RAILROAD 


Group  1 

Group  2 

Group  2 

Group  1 

Group  2 

Type  of 

Cost 
^1 

Mp^el 

A&A 

HNE 

CADIZ 

0.637 

PVS 

BC 

1 

0.297 

0.723 

-0.154 

0.678 

2 

0.170  a 

0.809 

0.780 

-0.193 

a 

0.718 

3 

^la 

0.213 

1.352 

1.007 

-0.294 

0.770 

4 

*a 

0.120  a 

1.426 

1.046 

-0.339 

0.755 

5 

«Ui 

0.095 

2.296 

1.113 

-0.754 

0.769 

6 

-0.051  a 

2.212 

1.125 

-0.876 

0.750 

7 

^u. 

0.399 

0.745 

0.032 

0.196 

0.769 

8 

0.385  a 

0.891  a 

0.384 

0.227 

a 

0.764 

9 

<=lb 

0.836 

0.636 

0.280 

-0.215 

0.453 

10 

0.901 

0.668  a 

0.530 

-0.221 

a 

0.499 

11 

Cl., 

0.737 

1.579 

1.111 

0.644 

0.752 

12 

0.909 

1.762  a 

1.072  a 

0.652 

a 

0.780  a 

13 

s 

0.796 

-0.628 

0.435 

-0.792 

-0.037 

14 

0.828 

-0.995  a 

0.711  a 

-0.830 

0.039  a 

15 

=1.3 

0.989 

1.883 

-0.182 

0.149 

1.225 

16 

1.069 

1,806  a 

0.144  a 

0.158 

a 

1.189 

17 

•=10 

0.117 

0.795 

-0.038 

-0.053 

0.903 

18 

-0,114 

0.855 

0.294 

-0.104 

a 

0.923 

19 

c, 

0.035 

1.362 

0.090 

0,012 

0.626 

20 

1=1 

-0.239 

1,495  a 

0.378 

-0.041 

a 

0.658 

21 

=lc, 

0.089 

4.260 

1,248 

0.027 

0.881 

22 

-0.195  a 

3.377 

1.154 

0.010 

a 

0.826 

23 

c, 

0.601 

3.770 

-0.300 

0.560 

1.475 

24 

Ic3 

0.497 

3.428 

-0.256  a 

0,649 

a 

1.466 

25 

^1C4 

0.200 

0.627 

-0.469 

-0.270 

1.143 

26 

0.035  a 

0.675  a 

-0.014  a 

-0.352 

a 

1.150 

27 

^Id 

0.270 

0,358 

1.431 

-0.098 

0.395 

28 

0.090  a 

0.299  a 

1.224 

-0.139 

a 

0.455 

29 

B 

-0.842 

0.860 

-0.471 

-0.313 

1.922 

30 

■  z 

-1.356  a 

0.771 

-0.033  a 

-0.362 

a 

1.789 

31 

E 

0.296 

-0.056 

-0.200 

0.062 

a;205 

32 

c 

0.131 

-0.158  a 

0.177 

0.051 

0.289 

33 

E^ 

0.691 

1.099 

-0.091 

-0.059 

0.219 

34 

t 

0.765  a 

1.097 

0.294  a 

-0.104 

a 

0.264  a 

35 

ALL 

0.281 

0.698 

0.490 

-0.134 

0.709 

36 

0.156  a 

0.752 

0.681 

-0.171 

a 

0.734 

TABLE  5  continued 


Group  1 

Group  1 

Group  . 

Group  2 

Group  1 

Type  of 

Cost 
^1 

Model 
I 

AMAD 
-0.009 

CoP 

APACHE 
-0.548 

MISS 
0.114 

c&c 

1 

0.066 

0.611 

2 

A 

II 

-0.031 

a 

0.163  a 

-0.452  a 

0.150  a 

0,609 

3 

«u 

I 

0.401 

-0.015 

-0.740 

-0,350 

1.218 

4 

II 

0.392 

a 

0.092  a 

-0.648  a 

-0.307  a 

1.206 

5 

'^, 

I 

0.484 

-0.024 

-1.103 

-0.246 

1.453 

6 

II 

0.475 

a 

-0.072  a 

-1.003  a 

-0,233  a 

1.441 

7 

s 

I 

-0.992 

0.713 

0,589 

-0.547 

0.787 

8 

II 

-0,978 

a 

0.719  a 

0.637  a 

-0.501 

0.776 

9 

hh 

I 

-1.309 

-0.118 

-1.250 

-0.258 

1.887 

10 

^u 

II 

-1.533 

a 

0.008  a 

-1.176  a 

-0.228  a 

1.792 

11 

<^lb, 

I 

-4.268 

-0.322 

-1.128 

-0.397 

0,221 

12 

i.Ol 

II 

-4.595 

a 

-0.149  a 

-0.994  a 

-0.478  a 

0,193  a 

13 

<=!., 

I 

0.203 

0,326 

0.550 

-0.350 

1,207 

14 

II 

0.129 

a 

0,401  a 

0.560  a 

-0.409  a 

1.160  a 

15 

^.3 

I 

2.489 

0.774 

-2.432 

-0.011 

2.339 

16 

II 

2.281 

a 

0.756  a 

-1.578  a 

0.023  a 

2.218 

17 

Ic 

I 

-0.196 

0.366 

-0.254 

0.444 

0.041 

18 

II 

-0.158 

a 

0.429 

-0.175  a 

0.472 

0.045  a 

19 

^ic, 

I 

-0.663 

0.493 

-0,505 

0,385 

-0.021 

20 

II 

-0.590 

a 

0.539 

-0.408  a 

0.370  a 

-0.021  a 

21 

^ic, 

I 

0.295 

0.744 

-1.777 

0.350 

-0.011 

22 

II 

0.338 

a 

0.768 

-1.664  a 

0,414  a 

0.022  a 

23 

^103 

I 

-3.906 

1.818 

0.311 

-0.065 

0.636 

24 

II 

-3.806 

1.692 

0.437  a 

0.028  a 

0.672  a 

25 

^Ic 

I 

0.901 

-0,238 

0.656 

0.573 

-0.073 

26 

^''4 

11 

0.875 

-0.104  a 

0.724  a 

0.592 

-0.060  a 

27 

^Id 

I 

0.146 

-0,708 

0.437 

0.447 

-0.015 

28 

11 

0.106 

a 

-0,542 

0.457  a 

0.476 

-0.024  a 

29 

E 

I 

0.152 

1.236 

-0.498 

1.829 

-1.450 

30 

r 

II 

0.228 

a 

1.204  a 

-0.449  a 

1.742 

-1.398  2 

31 

h 

I 

-0.137 

0.361 

0,305 

0.173 

0.302 

32 

II 

-0.115 

a 

0.438 

0.350 

0,227 

0.327  a 

33 

h 

I 

-0.609 

0.488 

0.942 

-0.121 

1.104 

34 

II 

-0.508 

0.532 

0,980  a 

-0.048  a 

1.^074 

35 

ALL 

I 

0.036 

0.200 

-0.351 

0.498 

0.204 

36 

II 

0.079 

a 

0.285  a 

-0.269 

0.517 

0.216  a 

•12- 


those  coefficients  with  the  wrong  sign,  however,  were  insignificant  at  the 
five  percent  level  and  were  designated  by  an  "a"  on  Table  3o  For  model  I, 
the  negative  elasticities  occur  vrtien  the  coefficient,  b,  of  InV  is  of  the 
correct  sign  but  large  relative  to  ACo  Usually  these  negative  signs  occur 
for  cost  items  that  are  very  small,  and  may  be  a  result  of  unsatisfactory 
deflators, 

(4)  Six  of  the  ten  elasticities  of  "ALL"  costs  are  very  low  (less 
than  .3).  Since  the  elasticity  is  the  ratio  of  marginal  to  average  cost, 
the  small  elasticities  indicate  that  these  firms  vrere  operating  on  the 
low-output  downward- sloping  portions  of  their  short  run  cost  curves,  and, 
therefore,  that  substantial  unused  capacity  existed  for  these  firms  during 
the  sample  time  period.  These  roads  are:  Arcade  &  Attica,  Pecos  Valley 
Southern,  Amador,  City  of  Prineville,  Apache,  and  Corinth  and  Counce. 

(5)  The  other  four  roads  have  elasticities  close  to  or  abov  .j. 
Although  an  increase  in  traffic  would  reduce  average  cost  ^^^r  these  roads, 
it  would  not  heve  the  substantial  impact  that  it  would  for  the  other  six 
roads.  These  four  roads  include:  HiHsboro  &  Northeastern,  Cadiz, 
Bellefonte  Central,  and  Mississippi  Export,  These  roads  were  likely 
operating  closer  to  minimum  short  run  average  cost  than  those  in  the  previous 
group--given  their  fixed  inputs, 

(6)  Average  costs,  marginal  costs,  and  the  elasticities  for  the  "ALL" 
cost  items  are  reported  in  Table  6  for  each  railroad.  They  illustrate  more 
clearly  how  the  costs  behave  with  a  change  in  traffic  of  1,000  ton-miles. 

(7)  To  gat  a  better  idea  of  the  responsiveness  of  total  cost  to  change 
in  volume,  average  elasticities  for  each  of  the  two  groups  of  railroads 


TABLE  6 

COSTS  AND  ELASTICITIES  FOR  THE  SAMPLE  RAILROADS 
CALCULATED  USING  MODEL  II  AND  THE  MEDIAN  VOLUME  OF  THE  ROAD 


Railroad 

AC/IOQOT-M 

MC/IOOOT-M 

®TC°T-M 

(1) 

AScA 

$542.40 

$  84.82® 

0.156 

(6) 

AMAD 

118.10 

9.29^ 

.079 

(8) 

APAC 

29.20 

-  7.86^ 

-  .269 

(5) 

BELC 

188.80 

138.57 

.734 

(3) 

CAD 

213.10 

145.10 

.681 

(7) 

CoP 

51.80 

14.75^ 

.285 

(10) 

C&C 

34.30 

a 
7.39 

.216 

(2) 

HNE 

237.90 

178.89 

.7'^'^ 

(9) 

MISS 

31.90 

16.48 

.517 

(4) 

PVS 

106.10 

-  18.13* 

-  .171 

Not  signlfJ  -antly  different  from  zr -o  at  the  five  percent  level. 


■13- 


described  ebove.  These  crude  average  elasticities  appear  in  Table  ?,,    For 
most  items,  the  elasticities  for  group  I  have  substantially  low3r  figures 
than  group  IIo  Tha  cost  items  which  have  higher  elasticity  for  group  I 
than  for  group  II  are:   Other  maintenance  of  way  (C,   ),  Maintenance  of 
equipment  (C^,  ),  Equipment  depreciation  (C,.  ),  Other  maintenance  of  equip- 
ment costs  (C.,  )5  and  Tax  payments  (E  ),  Although  C.   and  C.   are 
relatively  small  cost  components,  maintenance  of  equipment,  equipment 
depreciation,  and  tax  payments  represent  a  substantial  proportion  of  this 
group's  cost. 

(8)  There  are  three  cost  items  which  have  elasticities  of  apprcximutely 

unity  for  group  11.  These  are  roadway  maintenance  (Ci   ),  Locomotive 

ia^ 

repairs  (Civ^.  ),  and  Equipment  rentals  (E  )„  The  average  cost  of  these  cost 

items  did  not  change  with  an  increase  in  traffic.  The  high  elasticities  of 

the  first  two  presumably  reflect  "catch-up"  maintenancG  as  traffic  rises; 

the  third  simply  reflects  proportionately  greater  car  use.  Two  of  the  coct 

Items  for  group  II  were     much      greater  than  unity:  Trein  fuel 

costs  (C,   )  and  Costs  of  Iocs,  damnge,  casualties,  and  personal  injur-i- 
lc2 

(U,   ),  Ths  average  cost  of  these  items  actually  increased  with  an  increacc. 
in  traffic.  The  first  must  reflect  running  additional  trains  with  less 
volume  per  train;  the  second  is  likely  accidental. 

(9)  The   most  interesting  observations  vhich  can  be  aads  about  Table  7 
concern  those  elasticities  that  are  very  low.  The  lowest  two  elasticitier 


Wnen  a  negative  elasticity  appeared  in  Table  5,  it  was  considerec 
uo  hs   zero  when  these  average  elacticities  were  calculated. 


TABLE  7 
AVERAGE  ELASTICITIES,  VARIOUS  COST  CATEGORIES 


Type  of 

Cost 

Model 

Group  I 

Group  II 

1 

^ 

I 

.162 

.538 

2 

II 

.157 

.614 

3 

Cu 

1 

.305 

.782 

4 

II 

.302 

.807 

5 

^lan 

1 

.339 

1.045 

6 

**1 

II 

.319 

1.022 

7 

^lao 

I 

.447 

.387 

8 

2 

II 

.457 

.510 

9 

^Ib 

I 

.454 

.342 

,10 

II 

.450 

.424 

11 

^Ib, 

I 

.267 

.861 

12 

ADJ 

II 

.292 

.9039 

13 

^lb2 

I 

.514 

,109 

14 

II 

.513 

.188 

15 

Clb3 

I 

1.123 

.777 

16 

II 

1,080 

.791 

17 

he 

I 

.087 

.536 

18 

II 

«079 

.636 

19 

'^H 

I 

.090 

.616 

20 

II 

.090 

.725 

21 

^ICo 

I 

,193 

1,685 

22 

i.C2 

11 

.190 

1.443 

23 

^Ic 

I 

.663 

1.311 

24 

3 

II 

.658 

1.230 

25 

^Ic, 

I 

.293 

.586 

26 

"■^4 

II 

.272 

.604 

27 

^Id 

I 

.142 

.658 

28 

xu 

II 

.109 

.614 

29 

^r 

I 

.231 

1.128 

30 

II 

.239 

1.0755 

31 

E 

I 

.221 

.095 

32 

w 

II 

.296 

.173 

33 

Et 

I 

.538 

.330 

34 

la 

II 

.670 

.414      ' 

35 

ALL 

I 

.114 

.599 

36 

II 

.110 

.661 

TABLE  7 
AVERAGE  ELASTICITIES,  VARIOUS  COST  CATEGORIES 


Type  of 

Cost 

Model 

Group  I 

Group  II 

1 

c, 

I 

.162 

.538 

2 

1 

II 

.157 

.614 

3 

<=i. 

I 

.305 

.782 

4 

II 

.302 

.807 

5 

''^^ 

I 

.339 

1.045 

6 

II 

.319 

1.022 

7 

^Uo 

I 

.447 

.387 

8 

*OQ 

II 

.457 

.510 

9 

=ib 

I 

.454 

.342 

.10 

II 

,450 

.424 

11 

=1H 

I 

.267 

.861 

12 

II 

.292 

.9039 

13 

=u. 

I 

.514 

,109 

14 

II 

.513 

.188 

IS 

Clb3 

I 

1.123 

.777 

16 

II 

1.080 

.791 

17 

Clc 

I 

.087 

.^36 

18 

A\» 

II 

,079 

,636 

19 

^^=1 

I 

.090 

.616 

20 

II 

.090 

.725 

21 

=u, 

I 

.193 

1,685 

22 

II 

.190 

1,443 

23 

•^Ic 

I 

.663 

1,311 

24 

"3 

II 

.658 

1.230 

25 

% 

I 

.293 

.586 

26 

II 

.272 

.604 

27 

^Id 

I 

.142 

.658 

28 

II 

.109 

,514 

29 

h 

I 

.231 

1.128 

30 

II 

.239 

1.0755 

31 

E 

I 

.221 

.095 

32 

c 

II 

,296 

.173 

33 

h 

I 

.538 

.330 

34 

II 

.670 

.414 

35 

ALL 

I 

.114 

.599 

36 

II 

.110 

.661 

•14- 


for  group  I  are  Transportation-Rail  line  costs  (C,  )  and  the  subcategory 
of  this,  Emp''oyee  Compensation  (of  t-ain  crews)  (C,   ).  The  low  elasticitlas 
(almost  zero)  imply  that  average  labor  costs  will  decrease  substantially 
with  an  increase  in  traffic.  Two  other  subcategories  of  Transportation- 
Rail  line  costs  (C,  )  have  low  elasticities:  Train  fuel  costs  (C,   ) 
Ic  .  ■I-C2 

and  Other  transportation  costs  (C^   ),  The  very  low  elasticity  for  Train 

fuel  costs  (C,   )  indicates  that  an  increase  in  volume  will  allow  longer 
ic2 

trains  and  proportionately  less  switching  and  therefore,  more  efficient 
fuel  use.  An  inefficient  use  of  labor  for  low  levels  of  traffic  is  again 
indicated  by  the  low  elasticities  of  Locomotive  repairs  (C,,  ),  a  subcategory 
of  Maintenance  of  equipment  costs  (C,.  ),  and  Traffic,  administrative  and 
miscellaneous  costs  (C-,,).  The  low  elasticity  of  the  Rate  of  return  on 
railroad  equipment  (E  )  indicates  an  inefficient  use  of  equipment  at  low 
volumes  but  the  low  elasticity  of  Equipment  rentals  (Ej.)  is  difficult  to 
explain.  Total  operating  costs  (C,)  has  a  very  low  elasticity  as  well. 
This  is  simply  a  reflection  of  the  low  elasticities  of  the  cost  components 
of  Total  ope.ating  costs. 

Conclusion 

The  proposed  abandonments  of  many  light  density  lines  and  the  reorganiza- 
tion of  the  Northeastern  quadrant's  railroads  indicate  a  need  for  a  better 
knowledge  of  railroad  costs  and  revenues  for  evaluating  the  alternatives 
to  abandonment,  such  as  subsidies  or  converting  marginal  branch  lines  into 
either  privately  or  municipally  owned  short  lines. 

We  have  attempted  to  shed  some  light  on  the  responsiveness  of  the 
various  cost  components  of  low  density  railroads  to  a  change  in  traffic. 


■15- 


Our  results  show  that  for  all  roads  in  the  sample,  MC  is  well  below  AC, 
and  thus  add:'*:ional  traffic  will  redi-ce  AC.  For  six  of  the  ten  roads  in 
the  sample,  MC  is  extremely  low  and  additional  traffic  reduces  AC  dramatically; 
for  the  second  group,  the  reduction  is  less,  though  substantial.  The  two 
major  cost  categories,  train  operating  and  wage  costs  and  track  maintenance 
costs,  show  very  low  elasticities  for  the  first  group.  The  primary  difference 
between  the  two  groups  is  in  maintenance  costs,  suggesting  that  the  higher 
elasticity  of  the  second  group  is  due  to  catching  up  deferred  maintenance 
and,  therefore,  would  be  eliminated  if  a  period  of  two  or  three  years  was 
used  instead  of  one  year. 

The  basic  conclusion  therefore  is  that,  in  the  short  run,  additional 
traffic  on  light  traffic  lines  will  significantly  lower  train  operating 
and  maintenance  of  way  costs,  and  therefore  improve  the  financial  viability 
of  the  lines.  The  roads  are  typically  operating  well  below  capacity.   These 
.results,  however,  are  not  conclusive  about  the  ability  of  light  traffic 
lines  to  adjust  over  time  to  changed  volume  levels. 


aouNoJS