Skip to main content

Full text of "Specification error, random coefficient and the risk-return relationship test in capital asset pricing"

See other formats


UNIVERSITY  OF 

ILLlNOiS  LIBRARY 

pjURBAMA-CHA.^MGN 


Digitized  by  the  Internet  Archive 

in  2011  with  funding  from 

University  of  Illinois  Urbana-Champaign 


http://www.archive.org/details/specificationerr676leec 


f^^; 


Faculty  Working  Papers 


G>llege  of  Commerce  and  Business  Administration 

Univvrsity  of  Illinois  at  Urbana  -  Cho  mpoig  n 


FACULTY  WORKING  PAPERS 
College  of  Connnerce  and  Business  Adniinistration 
University  of  Illinois  at  Urbana-Champaign 
May  9,  1980 


SPECIFICATION  ERROR,  RANDOM  COEFFICIENT  AND  THE 
RISK-RETURN  RELATIONSHIP  TEST  IN  CAPITAL  ASSET 
PRICING 

Cheng  F.  Lee,  Professor,  Department  of  Finance 

Frank  J.  Fabozzi,  Hofstra  University 

Jack  Clark  Francis,  II,  Baruch  College,  CUNY 


#676 


Summary 

Both  specification  error  and  random  coefficient  concepts  are  used  to  show 
why  the  traditional  method  of  testing  the  risk-return  relationship  in  capital 
asset  pricing  may  not  be  appropriate.   Empirical  studies  of  capital  asset  pricing 
are  reviewed  in  detail  to  show  how  the  random  coefficient  behavior  can  occur  in 
the  estimated  parameters  of  the  equation  used  to  test  the  positive  theory  of 
capital  asset  pricing. 


SPECIFICATION  ERROR,  RANDOM  COEFFICIENT  AND  THE  RISK-RETURN 
RELATIONSHIP  TEST  IN  CAPITAL  ASSET  PRICING 


I.   INTRODUCTION 

The  theory  of  equilibrium  in  the  capital  markets  developed  inde- 
pendently by  Sharpe  (1964),  Lintner  (1965)  and  Treynor  (1961)  provides 
a  risk-return  relationship  for  assets  and  portfolios.  This  relation- 
ship, shown  as  equation  (1),  is  called  the  security  market  line  (SML) 
by  Sharpe  and  the  capital  asset  pricing  model  (CAPM)  by  others. 


(1)       E(R^)  =  E(R^)  +  B^[E(R^)-E(R^)] 

where  E(R, )  denotes  the  expected  rate  of  return  from  the  jth  market 

asset,  E(R.)  represents  the  expected  value  of  the  risk-free  interest 

rate,  B.  is  called  the  beta  systematic  risk  coefficient,  E(R  )  is  the 
2  '    m 

expected  return  from  the  market,  and 


[E(R  )  -  E(R-)]  is  the  theoretical  market  risk  premium. 
m      f 

The  risk-retvim  relationship  has  been  used  to  evaluate  portfolio 
performance,  test  for  market  efficiency,  determine  the  required  equity 
return  for  regulated  industries  and  approximate  the  hurdle  rate  for 
capital  investment  projects.  Because  of  the  pivotal  role  of  the 
relationship  in  financial  theory,  researchers  have  empirically  tested 
the  model  to  determine  if  the  estimated  parameters  are  equal  to  the 
theoretical  values.  Although  the  results  of  researchers  have  consis- 
tently rejected  the  hypothesis  that  the  estimated  and  theoretical 
values  are  equal,  the  findings  do  suggest  that  systematic  risk  is  a 
meaningful  measure  of  risk  and  stocks  with  high  systematic  risk  yield 


-2- 

correspondingly  higji  rates  of  return. 

This  paper  presents  the  empirical  results  of  a  different  test  of 
the  validity  of  the  risk  return  relationship.   Rather  than  estimate 
the  model  using  a  fixed  regression  coefficient  model  (as  is  suggested 
by  theory  since  the  market  risk  premivm  is  theoretically  constant  for 
all  securities) ,  a  stochastic  parameter  regression  model  is  tested. 
With  this  latter  model  the  market  risk  premium  can  be  tested  to 
determine  if  it  changes  randomly  from  security  to  security. 

The  next  section  provides  theoretical  reasons  to  justify  the  use 
of  a  stochastic  parameter  regression  model  to  describe  the  risk-return 
relationship.   Section  III  formulates  the  specific  stochastic  parameter 
model  employed.   The  data  and  resvilts  are  described  in  the  fourth  section, 
followed  by  the  conclusions  in  section  five. 

II.   JUSTIFICATION  FOR  EMPLOYING  THE  STOCHASTIC  PARAMETER  REGRESSION  MODEL 
The  empirical  analogue  of  equation  (1)  is  shown  as  equation  (2) . 


(2)       Rj  =  ^0  "^  ^l^j  ^  ®j 


where 


R.  =  the  arithmetic  mean  return  for  security  j 

3 

B.  =  the  estimated  systematic  risk  for  security  j,  and 
e.  =  the  stochastic  error  for  security  j 

Equation  (2)  is  estimated  using  cross-sectional  data  with  the  beta 
coefficient  estimated  from  a  first-pass  regression  based  on  a  time 


-3- 

series  of  historical  returns.   If  equation  (1)  is  a  true  description 
of  the  risk-return  relationshp,  then  X-.  and  X,  should  equal  the  arith- 
metic mean  return  for  the  risk-free  asset  (R-)  and  arithmetic  average 

excess  of  the  market  return  (R  )  over  the  risk- free  rate  (that  is,  the 

m 

market  risk  premium) .  Moreover,  the  slope  should  be  constant  for  all 

securities. 

In  a  survey  article  about  stochastic  parameter  regressions, 

3arr  Rosenberg  (1973,  p.  381)  states: 

The  stochastic  parameter  problem  arises  when  para- 
meter variation  includes  a  component  which  is  a 
realization  of  some  stochastic  process  in  addition 
to  whatever  component  is  related  to  observable 
variables.  Thus,  stochastic  parameter  regression 
is  a  generalization  of  ordinary  regression.   Ideally, 
a  model  would  be  so  well  defined  that  no  stochastic 
parameter  variation  would  be  present,  and  no  general- 
ization would  be  needed  J,  but  the  world  is  less  than 
ideal. 

If  the  risk-return  relationship  is  well  specified,  we  would  not  observe 

that  its  slope  or  market  risk  premium  would  vary  stochastically. 

However,  there  exist  both  theoretical  economic  and  econometric  reasons 

to  suspect  the  risk-return  relationship  is,  in  fact,  misspecified. 

First,  Arditti  (1967),  Kraus  and  Litzenberger  (1976)  and  others 

have  published  theoretical  and  empirical  work  showing  that  the  equil- 

ibrixmi  return  of  an  asset  is  influenced  by  both  the  second  and  third 

statistical  moments  of  its  return  distribution.  These  findings  extend 

the  two  parameter  model  to  a  third  parameter,  namely,  skewness.   Since 

the  risk-return  relationship  ignores  the  impact  of  skewness,  or  skew- 

2 
ness  related  factors,  it  suffers  from  omitted  variables. 

Second,  other  studies  have  suggested  the  possibility  of  additional 

emitted  variables.   Sharpe  (1977),  for  example,  has  given  the  risk- 


-4- 

retum  relationship  a  "multi-beta"  interpretation.   Similarly,  Ross 
(1976,  1977)  uses  an  arbitrage  approach  to  derive  a  multi-factor 
risk-return  relationship.  Brennan  (1970)  has  analyzed  the  impact  of 
the  tax  effect  due  to  the  different  treatment  of  dividend  income  and 
capital  gains.  He  derived  a  multi- index  model  including  average  excess 
dividend  yield  as  an  additional  explanatory  variable  in  the  risk-return 
relationship.  Bachrach  and  Calai  (1979)  have  s'hovm  that  the  price  of 
the  stock  should  be  included  in  the  risk-return  relationship  while 
Lanstein  and  Sharpe  (1978)  and  Joehnk  and  Petty  (1980)  have  shown  that 
duration  or  interest  rate  risk  should  also  be  considered. 

Statistically,  the  multi- index  risk-return  model  can  be  specified 
by  eqtiation  (3) . 

(3)  Rj  =  ^0  +  hh   ■"  ^2^^2j  +  •  •  •  +  Vnj  ■"  'i 

A,  A 

where  X_ ,  .  .  .,  X  are  estimates  of  omitted  factors  discussed  above, 
X_,  X  ,  X„ ,  ...  X  are  cross-section  regression  parameters,  and  t.  is 
the  stochastic  error  for  security  j.   It  should  be  noted  that  equation  (3) 
is  a  generalized  case  of  equation  (2) . 

If  we  use  the  specification  method  specified  by  Theil  (1971,  pp. 
548-549)  it  can  be  shown  that 

A         A  I  A  A 

(4)  X-  =  X,  +  b„X„  +  .  .  .  +  b  X 

1    1    z  z  n  n 

3 
where  b„,  b_,  .  .  .  b  are  so-called  auxiliary  regression  coefficients. 

In  addition  we  also  know  that 


5A)       ^0  "  ^j  "  ^l^j 


-5- 


and 

A|  _^  A|    AAA  A      ~ 

5B)  ^0  =  Rj   -  ^i3j  -  X2X2  -   .    .    .   -  W 

n     _  —  n     ^ 

where  R.   =     E     R./n,   e.   =     E     B./n 
J       j=l     ^  ^       j=l     ^ 

If  all  auxilliary  regression  coefficients  are  zero    (i.e.,   all  the 

A  A 

omitted  variables  are  independent  of  3.),  then  X.  is  an  unbiased  estimate 

A  f  A  A  f 

for  X- .  However,  X^  is  no  longer  an  unbiased  estimate  for  X^. 

A 

Therefore,  X^  cannot  be  used  to  test  the  null  hypothesis  that  Xq  is 
equal  to  R^  if  the  multi-index  model  is  appropriate.   If  equation  (3) 
does  hold  and  all  auxilliary  regression  coefficients  are  approximately 

A  A 

equal  to  zero,  X-  may  well  still  be  an  unbiased  estimator  of  X- .  However, 

A 

X^  becomes  a  random  instead  of  a  fixed  variable. 

Third,  Roll  (1977)  and  others  have  suggested  beta  estimates  obtained 
by  regressing  returns  from  common  stocks  on  stock  market  average  returns 
are  a  form  of  partial  equilibrium  analysis  which  ignores  investment  in 
other  capital  assets.  They  suggest  a  general  equilibrium  analysis 
which  includes  other  assets  (such  as,  investments  in  human  capital, 
commodities,  real  estate,  etc.)  should  be  used  to  obtain  a  risk-return 
tradeoff.   If  the  more  general  equilibrium  analysis  suggested  by  Roll 
produces  a  risk-return  relationship  which  departs  significantly  from 
the  usual  partial  equilibrium  analysis,  then  all  previous  empirical 
estimates  of  the  market  risk  premium  are  conceptuallly  flawed  and  may 
explain  why  the  model  may  exhibit  the  characteristics  of  a  stochastic 
parameter  regression  model. 

Fourth,  Levy  (1978)  and  Hessel  (1978)  have  demonstrated  that 
imperfect  capital  markets  will  modify  the  risk-return  relationship 


-6- 

which  is  predicated  on  the  assiimption  of  perfectly  competitive  markets. 
Levy  (1978),  for  example,  has  developed  a  generalized  risk-return 
relationship  when  (i)  market  participants  differ  in  their  investment 
strategies  and  do  not  adhere  to  the  same  risky  portfolio  given  by 
their  market  portfolio  and  (ii)  do  not  hold  many  risky  assets  in  their 
portfolio.  Levy  concludes  that  the  true  risk  index  is  somewhere  between 
the  total  variance  of  the  security  and  the  systematic  risk  implied  by 
capital  market  theory. 

Finally,  numerous  studies  have  documented  that  the  explanatory 
variable  in  the  risk-return  relationship,  the  beta  coefficient,  is  subject 
to  estimation  error.  The  beta  coefficient  is  estimated  in  the  first- 
pass  regression.  However,  in  the  first  pass  regression,  the  true  market 
model  may  be  a  multi-index  model  rather  than  a  single  index  model.  As 
indicated  in  the  discussion  of  the  second  pass  regression  above,  the 

estimated  beta  of  the  market  model  will  then  exhibit  the  characteristics 

4 
of  a  stochastic  parameter  regression  model. 

III.   TEST  FORMULATION 

Previous  research  employed  the  classical  OLS  fixed-coefficient 
approach  to  estimate  equation  C2) .  The  purpose  here  is  to  determine 
if  a  random  coefficient  relationship  between  return  and  systematic  risk 
exists.  That  is,  does  the  proportionality  constant,  X  ,  which  represents 
the  market  risk  premium  fluctuate  randomly  from  one  security  to  the  next? 

There  are  several  stochastic  parameter  regression  models  suggested  in  the 
literature.   The  random  coefficient  model  formulated  by  Thiel  (1971)  is 
used  in  this  investigation.  The  fixed  coefficient  model  given  by  equation 
(2)  can  be  converted  to  the  random  coefficient  model  (RCM)  shown  by 
equation  (6) . 


-7- 


(6)       R.  =  X_  +X,B.  +  w. 
J    0   1  J    J 


where 


and  X,  is  the  mean  of  X,  . .  Moreover,  it  is  assumed  that  the  distribution 
1  Ij 

of  X,  .  is  homoscedastistic  and  the  e.  values  are  uncorrelated  with  the 
Ij  J 

X,  .  values. 

To  test  whether  the  RCM  is  a  description  of  the  risk-return  relation- 
ship, two  statistics  must  be  estimated.  First  X  of  equation  (6),  and 
second,  the  variance  of  the  distribution  of  X  ,  around  its  mean  X  , 
var  (X  ) ,  must  be  estimated.   If  no  statistically  significant  variance 

for  X, .  around  X,  is  found,  then  the  RCM  can  be  rejected  and  the 

Ij        1 

traditional  fixed-coefficient  model  accepted. 

Theil  (1971,  p.  623)  has  shown  that  the  OLS  estimator  of  X 
in  equation  (6)  is  unbiased  but  will  result  in  an  inefficient  estimator 
for  the  variance  of  the  estimate  of  X  ,  var  C'*^-.^)*   The  procedure  suggested 
by  Theil  to  estimate  X  and  var(X^  .)  is  described  briefly  below. 

First,  the  ordinary  least  squares  residuals,  denoted  by  e.,  must 
be  calculated  from  equation  (2).   Second,  equation  (7)  must  be  estimated 
using  OLS. 

(7)       e?  =  m_P.  +  m,Q.  +  f . 


where 


J 
P.   =   1   -', 

*  2 


and 


f.  =  stochastic  error  term. 
3 

The  coefficients  m  and  dl.  are  to  be  estimated.  They  represent 
the  variance  of  the  error  term  in  eqiiation  (6)  and  var  (^]^^)» 
respectively.  The  statistical  significance  of  vl.    (as  measured  by  its 
t-statistic)  then  determines  whether  the  RCM  is  appropriate.  However, 
because  of  the  heteroscedasticity  in  equation  (7),  Theil  suggests  that 

Q 

eqiiation   (6)   be  estimated  using  generalized  least  squares    (GLS)  .        The 


GLS  estimate  for  X     in  equation    (Jo)   is  defined  in  equation   (8). 


(8)       X^  = 


No 


te  that  if  m^  is  not  statistically  different  from  zero,  equation  C8) 


reduces  to  the  OLS  estimate  for  X  . 

IV.   EMPIRICAL  RESULTS 

The  securities  used  to  estimate  the  risk-return  relationship  are 
the  common  stock  of  694  New  York  Stock  Exchange  companies.   For  each 
stock,  B.  was  estimated  from  the  single- index  market  model,  equation 
(9),  using  monthly  non-compounded  price  change  plus  dividend  returns 
for  the  72  month  period  from  Janiiary,  1966  to  December,  1971. 


C9)       R.  =  a.  +  g.R   +  u.^ 

jt    J   ""j  mt    jt 


-9- 


where 


R,  =  return  on  stock  i  in  month  t 
Jt 

R  ^  =  market  return  in  month  t 
mt 

u.^  =  stochastic  error  term  in  month  t  for  stock  i,  and, 
jt  j»    » 

a.  and  3.  are  the  parameters  to  be  estimated. 

The  S&P  500  index  with  dividends  included  was  used  for  the  market  index. 

The  time  period  was  also  partitioned  into  two  non-overlapping 
36  month  periods — January,  1966  to  December,  1968  and  January,  1969 
to  December,  1971.  Equation  (9)  was  estimated  for  both  time  periods. 
The  market  risk  premivim  was  positive  for  the  first  sample  period  and 
negative  for  the  second  sample  time  period. 

Estimates  of  the  fixed  coefficient  OLS  model  equation  C2)  for  each 
of  the  three  time  periods  are  presented  in  Table  1.  The  theoretical 
values  for  X  and  X  are  also  shown  in  Table  1.   For  each  time  period, 
the  signs  of  the  estimated  parameters  were  the  same  as  theory  suggests. 
And,  each  parameter  was  significantly  different  from  zero  at  the  1%  level 
of  significance.  Other  researchers  \Ao  estimated  the  risk-return 
relationship  found  that  the  estimated  values  for  the  parameters  were 
significantly  different  from  the  theoretical  values.  Table  1  suggests 
that  for  each  of  the  three  time  periods,  X^  was  significantly  different 
from  the  theoretical  value  of  the  market  risk  premium.  For  the  two  36 

month  time  periods,  X  was  not  statistically  different  from  the  theoretical 

9 
value,  R-. 


-10- 


The  results  for  X  and  m.  [=  var  (A  ,)]  for  the  RCM  are  summarized 
in  Table  1.  For  the  72  month  period,  the  variance  of  X   was  positive 
and  significantly  different  from  zero  at  the  5%  level  of  significance. 
This  was  also  found  for  the  36  month  period  January,  1966  to  December, 
1968  in  which  the  market  risk  premium  was  positive.  Hence,  for  the  two 
periods  in  which  the  market  risk  premiian  was  positive,  the  SML  was 
found  to  exhibit  the  property  of  a  RCM.  Howevier,  when  the  market  risk 
premium  was  negative,  namely,  from  January,  1968  to  December,  1971, 
the  variance  of  X  .  was  not  statistically  significant. 

It  is  also  interesting  to  note  the  degree  of  randomness  of  the 
market  risk  premiimi  for  the  two  cases  in  which  m  was  statistically 

/a     a 

significant.  The  coefficient  of  variation,^m  /X  ,  for  the  72  month 
and  36  month  time  periods  were  1.57  and  .97,  respectively.  This  indicates 
considerable  random  movement  in  relation  to  X  ,   If  a  95%  confidence 
interval  was  constructed  for  the  movements  around  X  based  onx/m^  ,  the 
interval  would  include  the  theoretical  value  for  the  market  risk  premium. 

V.   CONCLUSIONS 

The  risk-return  relationship  of  capital  market  theory  is  not  simply 
a  model  accepted  by  some  academicians.  Regulators  have  used  the  model 
to  estimate  the  appropriate  return  on  equity  for  regulated  firms. 
Corporate  management  has  been  encouraged  to  use  the  model  to  evaluate 
the  performance  of  in-house  or  independent  pension  portfolio  managers. 
The  performance  of  an  entire  industry  has  been  questioned  based  on 
empirical  results  which  have  used  the  theoretical  model.  We  must, 
therefore,  continue  to  evaluate  the  model  both  theoretically  and 
empirically. 


-11- 

In  this  paper,  we  disclose  a  disturbing  empirical  result  of 
the  risk- return  relationship.  Employing  a  stochastic  parameter 
regression  model,  we  find  that  the  market  risk  premium  varies  randomly 
from  one  security  to  the  next.  Moreover,  the  observed  randomness 
was  substantial.  General  plausible  explanations  for  such  results 
were  suggested.  Even  if  the  reader  rejects  any  or  all  of  these 
argunfints,  it  is  difficult  to  refute  the  empirical  findings.   It  is 
worthwhile  to  note  that  the  empirical  results  of  this  paper  have 
indirectly  supported  Roll  and  Ross's  (1979)  empirical  results  of 
testing  the  Arbirage  pricing  theory.    The  direct  relationship 
between  the  results  of  this  study  and  Roll  and  Ross's  results  will 
be  developed  in  the  future  research. 


-12- 

FOOTNOTES 

This  is  essentially  the  conclusion  reached  by  Modigliani  and 
Pogue  (1974)  in  their  review  of  the  empirical  tests  of  the  risk-return 
relationship.  Research  subsequent  to  that  reviewed  by  Modigliani  and 
Pogue  has  not  altered  that  conclusion. 

rrevious  research  on  skewness  and  the  risk-return  relationship 
is  summarized  in  footnote  2  of  Kraus  and  Litzenberger  (1976). 

A  more  precise  definition  can  be  found  in  Theil  (1971,  p.  549). 

This  was  found  true  for  a  substantial  number  of  stocks 
by  Fabozzi  and  Francis  (1978)  using  the  stochastic  parameter  regression 
model  described  in  the  next  section.   In  such  cases,  the  total  risk 
can  be  partitioned  as  follows: 

X  i 

where 

2 
0.     =  variance  for  the  returns  for  stock  i 

2 

a   =  variance  for  the  market  return 
m 

2 
a   =  unsystematic  risk  for  stock  i 

^i 
and 

2 
Ot,     =  variance  for  the  systematic  risk  of  stock  i 
o. 

1 

In  such  a  case,    equation   CI)    is  then 

R.   =  Xg  +  X^dl  +     aln/2     . 

"2 
Hence,  equation  (2)  is  misspecified  in  that  a       is  not  considered. 

Note  also  that  if  the  traditional  procedure  for  computing  unsystematic 

risk  is  employed  but  the  market  model  is  a  RCM,  then  the  unsystematic 

2  2 
risk  would  improperly  include  a     a    .  This  might  explain  why  some 

i  ™ 
researchers  have  found  a  positive  relationship  between  average  returns 

and  unsystematic  risk. 


-13- 

See. Rosenberg  (1973)  for  a  description  of  various  stochastic 
parameter  variation  models. 

This  inefficiency  results  from  the  fact  that  w.  in  equation 
(6)  is  heteroscedastic  [see  Theil  (1971,  pp.  623)].  -^This  may  help  explain 
why  Mller  and  Scholes  (1972)  found  heteroscedasticity  when  they 
estimated  equation  (2) . 

7  ^     — 

In  the  equations  below  B.  and  R,  represent  deviations  of 

each  variable  from  their  respective  means.   The  summation  is  over  all 

observations. 

g 
Theil  (1971)  has  shown  that  to  estimate  the  variance-covariance 

matrix  for  generalized  least  squares  in  this  case,  the  following  weights 

should  be  used: 

Z^  =  1/2  (^j  +  ^Q.)~^ 

where  Z.  =  the  weight  for  the  jth  observation  and  m-  and  m^  are  the 
ordinaiT'  least  sqxiares  estimates  of  nu   and  m^  for  eqxiation  (7), 

9 
This  result  was  scirfiwhat  surprising  in  light  of  the  analytical 

results  derived  in  Section  II.   It  was  shown  there  that  A-,  will  be  a 

biased  estimate  of  R^  if  the  multi-index  model  is  appropriate. 

A  one-tail  test  is  used  since  the  alternative  hypothesis  is 
that  the  variance  of  X^ .  is  positive. 

Roll  and  Ross  have  found  that  there  exist  at  least  three  and 
probably  four  "priced"  factors  in  addition  to  market  factor  in  the 
generating  process  of  return. 


-14- 


REFERENCES 


Arditti,  F.  D.  (1967),  "Risk  and  the  Required  Rate  of  Return," 
Journal  of  Finance  (March),  pp.  19-36. 

Bachrach  B.  and  Galai,  D.  (1969),  "The  Risk-Return  Relationship  and 
Stock  Prices,"  Joxirnal  of  Financial  and  Qtiantitative  Analysis 
(June),  pp.  421-442. 

Brennan,  M.  J.  (1970),  "Taxes,  Market  Valuation  and  Corporate  Financial 
Policy,"  National  Tax  Journal,  pp.  417-427. 

Fabozzi,  F.  J.  and  Francis,  J.  G.  (1978),  "Beta  as  a  Random  Coefficient," 
Journal  of  Financial  and  Quantitative  Analysis  (March) ,  pp.  101-115. 

Hessel,  C,  A.  (1978),  "The  Effects  of  Taxes  and  Imperfect  Competition  on 
an  Investor's  Optimum  Portfolio,"  unpublished  doctoral  dissertation. 
New  York  University. 

Joehnk,  M.  D.  and  Petty,  J.  W.  (1980),  "The  Interest  Sensitivity 

of  Common  Stock  Prices,"  Journal  of  Portfolio  Management  (Winter), 
pp.  19-25. 

Kraus,  A.  and  Litzenberger,  R.  H.  (1976),  "Skewness  Preference  and  the 
Valuation  of  Risk  Assets,"  Journal  of  Finance  (September),  pp. 
1084-1100. 

Lanstein,  R.  and  Sharpe,  W.  F.  (1978),  "Duration  and  Security  Risk," 
Journal  of  Financial  and  Quantitative  Analysis  (November),  pp. 
653-668. 

Levy,  H.  (1978),  "Equilibrium  in  an  Imperfect  Market:  A  Constraint  on 
the  Number  of  Securities  in  the  Portfolio,"  American  Economic 
Review  (September),  pp.  643-658. 

Lintner,  J.  (1965),  "The  Valuation  of  Risk  Assets  and  the  Selection 
of  Risky  Investments  in  Stock  Portfolios  and  Capital  Budgets," 
The  Review  of  Economics  and  Statistics  47  (February),  pp.  13-37. 

Miller,  M.  M.  and  Scholes,  M.  (1972),  "Rates  of  Returns  in  Relation 
to  Risk:  A  Re- examination  of  Recent  Findings,"  published  in 
Studies  in  the  Theory  of  Capital  Markets,  edited  by  Michael 
Jensen  Praeger,  pp.  47-78. 

Modigliani,  F.  and  Rogue,  G.  A.  (1974),  "An  Introduction  to  Risk 
and  Return,"  Financial  Analysts  Journal  (March-April) ,  pp. 
68-80;  (May-June),  pp.  69-86. 

Roll,  R.  (1977),  "A  Critique  of  the  Asset  Pricing  Theory's  Tests; 
Part  I:   On  Past  and  Potential  Testability  of  the  Theory," 
Journal  of  Financial  Economics,  (March),  pp.  129-176. 


-15- 


Roll,  R.  and  S.  A.  Ross  (1979),  "An  Empirical  Investigation  of  The 
Arbitrage  Pricing  Theory,"  Working  paper  15-79,  Gradiiate  School 
of  Management,  UCLA. 

Rosenberg,  B.  (1973),  "A  Survey  of  Stochastic  Regression  Parameters," 
Annals  of  Economic  and  Social  Measurement,  Vol.  2,  pp.  381-397. 

Ross,  S.  A.  (1976),  "Arbitrage  Theory  of  Capital  Asset  Pricing," 
Journal  of  Economic  Theory,  8,  pp.  341-360. 

Ross,  S.  A.  (1977),  "Return,  Risk  and  Arbitrage,"  In  I.  Friend  and 
J.  L.  Bicksler,  Risk  and  Return  in  Finance,  Vol.  1  (edited), 
Ballinger  Publishing  Company. 

Sharpe,  W.  F.  (1964),  "Capital  Asset  Prices:  A  Theory  of  Market 
Equilibrium  Under  Conditions  of  Risk,"  Journal  of  Finance,  • 
(September),  pp.  425-442. 

Sharpe,  W.  F.  (1977),  "The  Capital  Asset  Pricing  Model:  A  Multi-Beta 
Interpretation,"  in  Levy,  H.  and  M.  Samat,  eds.,  Financial 
Decision  Making  Under  Uncertainty,  (New  York:  Academic  Press, 
1977). 

Theil,  H.  (1971),  Principles  of  Econometrics,  John  Wiley  &  Sons. 

Treynor,  J.  L.  (1961),  "Toward  A  Theory  of  Market  Value  of  Risky 
Assets,"  unpublished  paper. 


CSl 


(0 

u 

i-l 

CO 

> 


O 

T-l 

u 
O 

<u 

H 


1 

II 


a-s 


o 

o 
o 


o 

3 
O 


in 


o 
o 


ii 


-3- 

o 
o 


o 

o 

o 


CO 

o 
o 


<U 

<    r< 

00 

<r 

rH 

-d 

N^ 

^ 

en 

Sf 

o 

S-l 

o 

o 

O 

^ 

nj 

o  .^ 

O   ^s 

o  ^-« 

> 

O   i>4 

o  o 

O  CO 

4-1 

O  r^ 

o  m 

O   SN 

c 

II 

•          • 

.    . 

.       . 

(U 

CM 

CM 

^^ 

•H 

-H 

V-' 

v-^ 

U 

<    S 

•H 

U-i 

H-l 

iH 

<u 

C/i 

O 

H 

O 

e 

-;r 

o 

in 

03 

o 

<r  -— ^ 

o  .^ 

•<r  /^ 

M 

w 

TS 

1-1 

O  I^ 

rH  r-» 

O     rH 

^ 

c 

<  ^ 

o  ^ 

O  VO 

O  c^ 

a 

cB 

.       . 

.      . 

•        • 

hJ 

fL4 

(iS 

in 

a\ 

1   -a- 

m 

o 

■^i^ 

^-^ 

1 

< 

>-/ 

H 

V2 

;g 

»a-  ^-N 

00  -— > 

00  .^ 

cs 

m  o 

in  in 

rH    CO 

M 

o  m 

rH    00 

O    vO 

u 

.    . 

.       . 

.       . 

c 

0^ 

<3^ 

C^4 

S 

ro 

CM 

r-l 

tI 

v-^ 

r-^ 

^-^ 

U 

>w^ 

•rl 

U^ 

vO 

in 

•J3 

tU 

•<r  /-^ 

O     /-N 

CO   ^-^ 

0) 

iH 

O  I~- 

rH    CO 

o  00 

o 

<  ^ 

O    CM 

O   CO 

o  m 

CJ 

1    en 

-o 

'w' 

rH 

1 

01 

s.-' 

N,-/ 

>4 

•H 

In 

O 

O    30 

O   <T> 

O    CM 

<  ^ 

o  Dec.        .0 
(2.7 

o  Dec.        .0 
(3.9 

o  Dec.        .0 

(2.8 

T3 

tj 

u 

u 

0 

•H 

^ 

so 

3^ 

M 

^ 

vO 

^ 

OJ 

<Ti 

ty> 

ON 

P-( 

■H 

rH 

rH 

<u 

•   iH 

•    00 

•    1-i 

a 

a  t-^ 

S  '^ 

C  f- 

•H 

03    CT\ 

co  a\ 

CO   CT\ 

H 

n  •H 

1-)     rH 

n  T-^ 

• 

<a 

CM       J= 

U 

u 

m 

u 

C3 

nJ 

t3 

o 

(U 

u 

u 

0) 

o 

M 

c 

0) 

a 

-a 

o 
u 

a 

4H 

•H 

4-1 

c 

c 

o 

(U 

•H 

i-> 

U 

0) 

to 

MH 

a 

I4H 

t 

•H 

u 

01 

p^ 

u 

rH 

<u 

4J 

XI 

c 

• 

nj 

rH 

MH 

o 

*^ 

O 

•H 

5\ 

<*H 

rH 

Cfl 

•H 

U 

c 

. 

c 

{JO 

u 

<u 

•H 

<u 

•H 

U3 

a 

o 

•H 

(U 

o 

>4H 

u 

4-1 

UH 

tC 

(U 

CM 

o 

33 

vO 

o 

(U 

CT\ 

3 

iH 

(U 

rH 

4= 

ClJ 

. 

H 

> 

c 
to 

T3 

•^ 

• 

<U 

4J 

4-1 

T3 

§ 

§ 

O 
•H 

•H 

•H 

M 

O 

4-1 

<U 

•H 

(fl 

Cl4 

I4H 

0) 

MH 

0) 

O 

rH 
rH 

a 

O 

< 

4J 

T3 

<u 

OJ 

« 

^ 

4J 

0) 

4J 

fO 

3 

g 

rH 

u 

•H 

to 

o 

J-i 

> 

I4H 

CO 

1 

di 

f^ 

S 

<u 

OJ 

rr 

^ 

MH 

4J 

4-1 

o 

S 

03 

<u 

o 

4J 

4J 

<-\ 

fl 

CO 

<J 

0) 

a 

,a 

03 

•H 

<U 

U 

C 

u 

03 

3 

o. 

0) 

o 

0) 

J2 

M 

(U 

en 

J= 

CM 

4-1 

Qi 

M 

U 

^ 

(3 

5 

o 

o 

yn 

03 

rH 

<U 

<U 

4-> 

3 

^ 

D. 

^ 

<U 

CO 

<u 

U 

> 

3 

;< 

1 

rH 

(U 

H 

CO 

> 

rH 

01 

CU 

X 

4) 

> 

H 

^ 

(U 

rH 

H 

rH 

Pd 


c 

>H 

3 

4J 

0) 

0) 

u 

HH 

I 

CQ 


0) 


0) 

!h 

3 

<a 
to 

0) 

e 


13 
(U 
CO 

3 

(U 

I-l 
to 


m 
>. 

M 

3 

03 

CO 
(U 

!-i 
H 

u 

a 
o 

e 

<u 

0) 
M 


a 

o 

iH 


CO 
T3 

rH 


4J 

i 

(U 
60 

to 

U 
0) 

> 
to 


3-9i