Skip to main content

Full text of "Stochastic duration and dynamic measure of risk in financial futures"

See other formats


UNIVERSITY  OF 

ILLINOIS  LIBRARY 

AT  URBANA-CHAMPAIGN 

BOOKSTACKS 


H 

or 

V 


JUST 


THE  HECKMAN  BINDERY,  INC. 
North  Manchester,  Indiana 


FONT 


H  CC    1W  ? 


SLOT        TITLE 
R 

JULTY 
'RKXNG 
19  PAPER 


H  CC  1W   8  19-34 

7  NO. 1050-1070 


H  CC  1W 


7W 


330 

B385<"CV"> 
no. 1050-1070 
cop.  2 

<IMPRINT> 
U.  of  ILL. 
LIBRARY 
URBANA 


)M] 


PERIODICAL     D  CUSTOM         D  STANDARD       D  ECONOMY       D  THESIS 
BOOK      Q  CUSTOM 


BINDING  COPY 


NO.  VOLS. 
THIS  TITLE 


66672    001 

ACCOUNT  NAME 


UNI      ILLINOIS 

ACCOUNT  INTERNAL  I.D. 


FOIL 

6632      WHI 


400 

I.D.  #2 

STX4 

COLLATING 

35 


NOTES    I  BINDING  WHEEL 

FREQUENCY 


SYS.  I.D. 


A 


V 


ADDITIONAL  INSTRUCTIONS 

Dept=STX4  Memo-[BD  W/O  NO  10 
BIND  IN       j  Lot=201  T*-a»*U8 

ZY#  BW91] 


SEP.  SHEETS 


PTS.  BD  PAPER 


POCKETS 


PAPER  I   BUCK 


INSERT  MAT 


TAPE  STUBS 


SPECIAL  PREP 


CLOTH  EXT. 


GUM 


FILLER 


PRODUCT  TYPE 
11 


HEIGHT. 


7/ 


ACCOUNT  LOT  NO. 

201 

ACCOUNT  PIECE  NO. 


GROUP  CARD 


COVER  SIZE 

X 


VOL  THIS 

TLF. 


TITL 


JOB  NO. 


PIECE  NO. 


001079 


330 

B385 

1063  COPY  2 


FACULTY  WORKIxNG 
PAPER  NO.  1063 


Stochastic  Duration  and  Dynamic  iMeasure  cf 
Risk  in  Financial  Futures 

Andrew  H.  Chen 
Hun  Y.  Park 
K.  John  Wei 


SEP"188*   . 


College  of  Commerce  and  Business  Administration 
Bureau  of  Economic  and  Business  Research 
University  of  Illinois,  Urbana-Champaign 


BEBR 


FACULTY  WORKING  PAPER  NO.  1063 
College  of  Commerce  and  Business  Administration 
University  of  Illinois  at  Urbana-Champaign 
July  1984 


Stochastic  Duration  and  Dynamic  Measure  of 
Risk  in  Financial  Futures 


Andrew  H.  Chen 
Southern  Methodist  University 

Hun  Y.  Park,  Assistant  Professor 
Department  of  Finance 

K.  John  Wei 
University  of  Mississippi 


Digitized  by  the  Internet  Archive 

in  2011  with  funding  from 

University  of  Illinois  Urbana-Champaign 


http://www.archive.org/details/stochasticdurati1063chen 


Abstract 

Combining  the  contributions  of  Cox,  Ingersoll  and  Ross  (1979,  1981) 
in  stochastic  duration  of  bonds  and  in  equilibrium  pricing  of  futures 
contracts,  this  paper  develops  stochastic  duration  as  a  dynamic  risk 
measure  for  financial  futures.   Some  simulation  results  are  provided  and 
discussed. 


Stochastic  Duration  and  Dynamic  Measure  Of 
Risk  In  Financial  Futures 

The  introduction  of  futures  contracts  on  several  financial  instru- 
ments into  the  exchanges  in  the  recent  years  has  generated  a  great  deal 
of  interests  in  studying  the  role  of  financial  futures.   Most  of  the 
studies  on  financial  futures  have  focused  either  on  the  empirical  inves- 
tigation of  hedging  effectiveness  of  financial  futures  or  on  deriving 
optimal  hedge-ratios  in  immunization  strategies  with  financial  futures 
using  Macaulay's  duration  as  a  risk  measure.    To  the  best  of  our  knowl- 
edge, no  study  on  financial  futures  to  date  has  explicitly  examined  the 
validity  of  using  the  traditional  duration  or  proposed  any  alternative 
risk  measure  in  the  immunization  strategies  with  financial  futures. 

As  Leibowitz  (1981)  has  demonstrated,  there  are  two  basic  kinds  of 
yield-curve  movements — parallel  market  shifts  and  yield-curve  reshapings — 
and  they  lead  to  fundamentally  different  types  of  volatility  behavior  in 
the  prices  of  financial  futures.   In  particular,  the  prices  of  financial 
futures  have  been  shown  to  be  extremely  sensitive  to  the  yield-curve  re- 
shapings  even  when  the  cash  security's  yield  remains  unchanged.   The  risk 
embedded  in  a  financial  futures  contract  is  not  the  same  as  that  of  a 
cash  security.   Therefore,  determining  a  proper  risk  measure  in  financial 
futures  is  of  significant  importance  if  we  attempt  to  devise  effective 
hedging  strategies  with  financial  futures  in  the  management  of  bond  port- 
folios. 

The  traditional  measures  of  duration,  developed  by  Macaulay  (1938) 
and  Hicks  (1939),  have  been  used  as  measures  of  basis  risk  of  bonds  and 
as  means  to  devise  immunization 'strategies  for  bond  portfolio  management. 


-2- 


The  concept  of  traditional  measures  of  duration  has  also  been  extended 

to  assess  the  risk,  of  other  financial  assets  such  as  common  stocks  and 

2 
financial  futures."   However,  as  Cox,  Ingersoll  and  Ross  (1979)  (CIR 

hereafter),  and  Ingersoll,  Skelton  and  Weil  (1978)  have  pointed  out,  the 
traditional  duration  is  a  valid  risk  measure  only  for  parallel  shifts  in 
the  entire  yield-curve  (i.e.,  preserving  yield-curve  shapings).   There- 
fore, applying  the  traditional  measures  of  duration  to  financial  futures 
for  immunization  strategies  (e.g.,  Chance  (1982),  and  Kolb  and  Chiang 
(1982))  might  lead  to  improper  results.   CIR  (1979)  has  developed  a 
"stochastic  duration"  which  has  been  shown  to  be  a  superior  alternative 
for  measuring  the  basis  risk  of  bonds. 

The  purpose  of  this  paper,  combining  the  contributions  of  CIR  (1979, 
1981)  in  the  stochastic  duration  of  bonds  and  in  the  equilibrium  pricing 

of  futures  contracts,  is  to  develop  stochastic  duration  as  a  dynamic 

3 
risk  measure  for  financial  futures.    It  is  our  hope  that  this  paper 

will  increase  the  understanding  about  the  risk  of  financial  futures  and 

thus  give  some  insights  for  more  efficient  immunization  strategies  in 

bond  portfolio  management.   Section  I  reviews  the  literature  on  duration 

of  bonds.   Section  II  develops  the  stochastic  duration  of  financial 

futures  and  shows  some  simulation  results.   Section  III  contains  a  brief 

summary. 

I.   Duration  of  Bonds:   Literature  Review 
Duration  of  a  bond,  originally  developed  by  Macaulay  and  Hicks, 
ed  as  a  weighted  average  of  times  to  maturity.   The  weight 
assigned  to  each  period  is  the  present  value  of  the  cash  flow  for  that 
od  divided  by  the  current  price  of  the  security  as  follows: 


-3- 

D  =  2  tC(t)P(t)/2  C(t)P(t)  (1) 

where  C(t)  is  the  stream  of  cash  flows  (coupons  and  principal  repay- 
ment) and  P(t)  is  the  present  value  of  $1.00  to  be  received  at  time  t. 
Duration  in  (1)  can  also  be  expressed  in  the  form  of  an  elasticity: 

-D  =  [(dB/B)/(dy/y)]/y  =  [dB/B] • [1/dy]  (2) 

— yt 
where  B  =  Z   C(t)e    and  y  is  the  continuously  compounded  yield-to- 
maturity  on  the  bond. 

CIR  (1979)  has  demonstrated  that  measuring  the  risk  of  a  bond  by 
the  elasticity  given  in  (2),  which  is  common  in  the  bond  market,  is 
faulty  since  the  result  in  (2)  cannot  be  used  to  make  cross-sectional 
comparisons  of  the  riskiness  of  bonds  (p.  52).   In  addition,  Ingersoll, 
Skelton  and  Weil  (1978)  has  proved  that  the  duration  in  (1)  can  be  a 
valid  risk  measure  only  when  the  entire  yield  curve  is  described  by 
proportional  shape-preservation  under  interest  rate  changes  (see  also 
CIR  (1979)  and  Bierwag,  Kaufman  and  Toevs  (1982)).   Thus  it  would  be 
misleading  if  we  apply  the  concept  of  the  traditional  duration  directly 
to  the  financial  futures  contract  since,  as  Leibowitz  (1981)  has  shown, 

the  futures  price  is  more  sensitive  to  yield  curve  reshapings  than  to 

4 
parallel  shifts. 

As  an  alternative,  CIR  (1979)  has  proposed  stochastic  duration  as 
a  dynamic  measure  of  risk  of  bonds  with  units  of  time.   This  concept 
of  duration  allows  the  yield  curve  changes  in  shape  as  well  as  location, 
To  derive  the  stochastic  duration,  CIR  assumed  that  the  instantaneous 
compounding  risk-free  interest  rate,  r,  follows  the  first-order  auto- 
regressive  process  as 


-£- 


dr  =  <(u  -  r)dt  +  a/7  dz  (3) 

where  1J  is  steady— state  mean  and  <  is  the  parameter  for  the  speed  of 
adjustment  toward  u. 

Based  upon  a  general  process  for  interest  rate  in  (3),  they  derived 
the  stochastic  duration  as  a  proxy  for  basis  risk  of  coupon  bonds  with 
the  units  of  time  as  follows: 

D  =  G_1[-Br/B]  =  G_1[-E  C(t)Pr(t)/2  C(t)P(t)]  (4) 

=  G_1[E  C(t)P(t)C(t)/S  C(t)P(t)] 

where  P(t)  =  the  price  of  a  unit  discount  bond  with  time  to  maturity  T 

=  A(T)exp[-rG(t)] 

f  ]   2<u/o2 

.,    ,         )         2y   exp[(Y  +   <  +   X)x/2]  { 

K    J        |(Y   -    <  +    X)[exp(YT)    -    1]    +   2Yf 

G(t)    =   2/[<  +   X  +  Y   Coth(YT/2)] 
Y  -    [(<  +   X)2   +   2a2]1/2 
-a  =    the   parameter   for   the   market's    liquidity   preference 

r~1f    \        2   r    .K_ir2         K  +    X" 
G      (x;   =  —  Coth 


Y  LTx  Y 


CIR  (1979)  has  compared  the  traditional  duration  in  (1)  with  the 
stochastic  duration  in  (4),  and  concluded  that  the  traditional  duration 
is  not  theoretically  and  empirically  realistic. 

II.   Stochastic  Duration  of  Financial  Futures 
Taking  into  account  the  marking-to-market  effect  in  futures  con- 
explicitly,  CIR  (1981)  has  derived  the  equilibrium  pricing  for- 
mula for  the  futures  contract  on  a  unit  discount  bond. 


-5- 

Let  F(t,A)  be  the  futures  price  as  of  time  t  for  a  contract  with 
the  maturity  date  s  on  a  discount  bond  paying  one  dollar  at  time  T 
(t  <  s  <  T),  and  let  A  =  T  -  s  and  T  =  T  -  t  to  be  consistent  with  the 
notation  in  section  I.   Then  the  equilibrium  price  of  this  futures  con- 
tract is  as  follows: 


F(t,A)  =  A(A) 


where  n(s-t)  = 


n(s-t) 


G(A)  +  n(s-t) 


2(<  +  X) 


2<M/a 


•  exp 


l(s-t)G(A)e-(<+X)(s-t)l 
1    G(A)  +  n(s-t) 


2M    -(<+X)(s-tK 

a  (1  -  e  ) 


Using  (4)  and  (5),  the  stochastic  duration  of  the  futures  contract  on 

the  discount  bond  (D^)  can  be  derived  as 

F 


D   i  G  1[-F  /F] 

r         r 


=  G 


-1 


n(s-t)-G(A)e 


-(<+X)(s-t) 


G(A)  +  n(s-t) 


(6) 


=  G  X(x) 


(5) 


We  can  also  develop  the  pricing  formula  for  a  futures  contract  on 
a  coupon  bond  since  a  coupon  bond  can  be  regarded  as  a  portfolio  of 
discount  bonds.   Consider  a  coupon  bond  which  pays  n  constant  coupons 
(C)  with  tfhe  equal  time  interval  (5)  for  the  period  A  =  T  -  s  and  prin- 
cipal of  one  dollar  at  time  T,  i.e.,  A/6  =  n.   This  coupon  bond  can  be 
thought  of  as  a  portfolio  of  n  discount  bonds  (i  =  l,2,...,n).   Let 
F(t,iS)  be  the  futures  price  on  ith  discount  bond.   The  futures  price 
on  the  coupon  bond  as  of  time  t  (f(t))  can  be  written  as 


f(t)  = 


-6- 


C  Z      F(t,iS)  +  F(t,n<5) 
i=l 


(7) 


=  C  Z     A(i5) 
i=l 


— ,2<p/a* 


n(s-t) 


G(i6)  +  n(s-t) 


exp 


ln(s-t)G(i6)e-(<+A)(s-t)[ 
G(iS)  +  n(s-t)    C 


+  F(t,n5) 


Following  the  same  procedure,  using  (4)  and  (7),  the  stochastic  dura- 
tion of  the  futures  contract  on  a  coupon  bond  can  be  written  as 


Df  =  G'Vfr/f] 


-  G 


-1 


CZF(t,l6)(T'(s-t>G^g^"(^)CS"t)|  +  F(t  n,wn(S-t)G(n6)e-(<+X) 

! ! G(i6)  +  n(s-t)    !  +  ^W    G(n6)  ;  n(s_t) 


)(s-t) 


1 


CEF(t,i6)  +  F(t,n6) 


-  G"1(x) 


Equation  (3)  is  the  general  form  of  stochastic  duration  for  finan- 
cial securities.   For  instance,  if  C  is  zero  for  discount  bonds,  then 
(8)  reduces  to  (6)  and  we  have  Df  =  Dp.   In  addition,  when  t  is  equal 

s,  a  futures  contract  on  a  coupon  bond  becomes  a  cash  coupon  bond 
and  thus  (8)  reduces  to  (4). 

Although  the  results  in  (6)  and  (8)  appear  to  be  complicated,  their 
•ractical  application  is  not  as  restrictive  as  it  Looks  once  the  Para- 

of  the  interest  rate  process  in  (3)  are  estimated.   For  illustra- 
ion,  we  have  simulated  the  stochastic  durations  of  financial  futures 
using  the  parameter  values  in  (3)  estimated  by  CIR  (1979). 
Lme  series  of  the  weekly  auction  rates  on  91-day  Treasury  bills 
76,  CIR  has  estimated  <  =  .692,  p  =  5.623%,  and  a2   =    .00608. 


-7- 

Table  1  presents  the  simulation  results  on  stochastic  durations  of 
futures  contracts  on  discount  bonds  and  coupon  bonds  with  varying  coupon 
rates  and  time  periods.   We  have  assumed  M  =  r  and  X    (liquidity  premium) 
=  0  to  see  only  the  effects  of  uncertainty.   We  have  also  used  the  re- 
version parameter,  <  =  .692,  in  order  to  highlight  the  effect  of  interest 
rate  process  with  drift  affecting  the  shape  as  well  as  the  location  of 
the  yield  curve,  as  opposed  to  the  random  walk  with  zero  drift  affecting 
the  location  only. 

Table  1  demonstrates  that  the  stochastic  duration  of  futures  con- 
tracts on  bonds  decreases  as  coupon  rate  increases,  which  is  consistent 
with  the  duration  of  cash  bonds.   It  also  shows  that  as  s-t  becomes 
longer  for  the  given  period  of  A,  the  stochastic  duration  becomes 
smaller.   This  result  is  not  surprising,  since  the  futures  contract  as 
of  time  t  with  the  maturity  date  s  on  a  bond  maturing  at  time  T  can  be 
viewed  conceptually  as  a  portfolio  going  long  in  the  bond  with  the 
maturity  date  T  and  at  the  same  time  going  short  in  the  bond  maturing 
at  time  s.    Thus,  the  duration  of  the  futures  contract  can  be  inter- 
preted as  the  difference  between  the  duration  of  the  bond  maturing  at 
time  T  and  the  duration  of  the  bond  maturing  at  time  s.   In  addition, 
the  results  in  Table  1  are  consistent  with  the  notion  of  CIR  (1979) 
that  the  stochastic  duration  need  not  be  an  increasing  function  of 
maturity. 

However,  Table  1  is  not  directly  comparable  to  CIR  (1979)  because 
of  the  different  underlying  securities.   Table  2  presents  an  indirect 
comparison  between  the  stochastic  duration  of  cash  bonds  reported  in 
CIR  (1979)  and  the  stochastic  duration  of  futures  contracts  on  the  same 


-3- 

bonds  when  Che  time  period  until  the  maturity  of  the  futures  contracts 
is  extremely  short.   As  expected,  under  this  circumstance,  they  are 
quite  similar. 

It  is,  however,  important  to  note  that  the  stochastic  duration  of 
financial  futures  developed  in  this  paper  is  very  sensitive  to  the 
reversion  parameter.  Table  3  demonstrates  the  sensitivity  of  the 
stochastic  duration  to  the  reversion  parameter  <,  This  clearly  indi- 
cates that  the  effectiveness  of  the  stochastic  duration  for  practical 
applications  critically  depends  on  correct  estimates  of  parameters  in 
the  interest  rate  process  specified  in  (3). 

Once  the  aforementioned  stochastic  durations  for  cash  bonds  and  the 
futures  on  the  bonds  are  estimated,  they  can  be  utilized  to  calculate 
the  hedge  ratios  in  the  immunization  strategies  with  financial  futures. 
Since  the  stochastic  duration  for  financial  futures  developed  in  this 
paper  allows  for  parallel  shifts  as  well  as  reshapings  in  the  yield- 
curve,  it  must  be  a  better  risk  measure  and  it  will  provide  a  more 
effective  means  in  immunization  strategies  for  bond  portfolio  manage- 
ment.  However,  the  focus  of  this  paper  is  on  developing  stochastic 
duration  as  dynamic  measure  of  risk,  of  financial  futures  and  thus  the 
effectiveness  of  the  stochastic  duration  for  such  practical  application 
is  beyond  the  scope  of  the  current  paper. 

III.   Conclusion 

The  concept  of  duration  has  been  commonly  used  as  a  measure  of 
basis  risk  of  bonds.   However,  the  usefulness  of  the  traditional  dura- 

i  and  its  extentions  is  restrictive  both  theoretically  and  empiri- 
cally because  they  are  valid  only  for  parallel  market  shifts  in  the 


-9- 

entire  yield  curve.   Since  the  prices  of  financial  futures  contracts 
are  very  sensitive  to  yield-curve  reshapings,  the  traditional  duration 
provides  little  usefulness  in  immunization  strategies  with  financial 
futures.   We  have  developed  stochastic  duration  of  a  financial  futures 
contract  as  a  proxy  for  its  dynamic  measure  of  risk,  based  on  a  more 
realistic  interest  rate  process  allowing  changes  in  shape  as  well  as 
location  of  the  yield  curve  suggested  by  CIR  (1979).   The  simulation 
results  confirm  the  validity  of  the  aforementioned  stochastic  duration 
as  a  risk  measure  for  financial  futures. 


-10- 

Footnotes 

1See  Bacon  and  Williams  (1976),  Chance  (1982,  1983),  Ederington 
(1979),  Hill  and  Schneeweis  (1980),  and  Kolb  and  Chiang  (1981,  1982). 

2 
See  Boquist,  Racette  and  Schlarbaum  (1975),  Bierwag  (1977),  Bierwag 

and  Kaufman  (1979),  Chance  (1982,  1983),  Khang  (1979),  Kolb  and  Chiang 

(1981,  1982),  and  Williams  and  Pfeiger  (1982). 

3 
Futures  contracts  do  not  require  initial  investment.   Therefore  it 

seems  difficult  to  interpret  the  duration  of  futures  contracts.   How- 
ever, as  CIR  (1981)  and  Ingersoll  (1982)  pointed  out,  although  not  the 
price  of  an  asset,  a  futures  price  satisfies  the  same  equilibrium  as 
asset  prices.   The  payoffs  of  a  futures  contract  can  be  duplicated  by  a 
portfolio  containing  call  and  put  options  (see  Black  (1976)).   Also,  a 
futures  contract  can  be  interpreted  as  a  portfolio  yielding  positive  and 
negative  cash  flows  (see  Little  (1984)):   "A  long  position  implies  an 
outflow  at  the  delivery  date  and  subsequent  inflows  from  Che  delivered 
instrument"  (pp.  285).   In  any  case,  the  duration  of  a  futures  contract 
can  be  defined  as  the  duration  of  an  asset,  in  much  the  same  manner  as 
wealth  fractions  of  futures  contracts  in  investors  portfolio  are  defined 
in  the  literature  (see  Breeden  (1979)). 

4 
See  Kolb  and  Chiang  (1982)  for  application  of  the  concept  of 

Macaulay's  duration  to  futures  contracts. 

All  arguments  about  futures  contracts  (including  derivation  of 
stochastic  duration)  have  been  done  also  for  forward  contracts.   The 
results  on  forward  contracts  are  not  reported  here  but  will  be  avail- 
able upon  request. 

6 
Note  that  the  duration  of  a  futures  contract  on  the  discount  bond 

is  not  equivalent  to  the  duration  of  the  discount  bond  itself  which  is 

equal  to  the  maturity.   Also,  the  correctness  of  (6)  can  be  easily 

checked  by  deriving  the  duration  of  cash  discount  bond  with  the 

maturity,  s-t 

D   _  G-l  C(s)P(s-t)G(s-t) 


s  C(s)P(s-t) 


=  G"1[G(s-t)] 


=  s-t 

'See  CIR  (1979)  for  the  effect  of  <. 

8 
See  Little  (1984)  for  the  interpretation  of  futures  contracts  in 

much  the  same  wav. 


-11- 


Ref erences 


Bacon,  P.  and  Williams,  R.   1976.   "Interest  Rate  Futures:   New  Tool 
for  the  Financial  Manager,"  Financial  Management  (Spring):   32-38. 

Black,  F.   1976.   "The  Pricing  of  Commodity  Contracts,"  Journal  of 
Financial  Economics  3:   169-179. 

Boquist,  J.  A.,  Racette,  G.  A.,  and  Schlarbaum,  G.  G.   1975.   "Duration 
and  Risk.  Assessment  for  Bonds  and  Common  Stocks,"  Journal  of 
Finance  30:   1360-1365. 

Bierwag,  G.  0.   1977.   "Immunization,  Duration  and  the  Term  Structure 
of  Interest  Rates,"  Journal  of  Financial  and  Quantitative  Analysis, 
Vol.  12  (December):   725-742. 

and  Kaufman,  G.  G.   1979.   "Coping  with  the  Risk  of  Interest 


Rate  Fluctuations:   A  Note,"  Journal  of  Business,  Vol.  50  (July): 
364-370. 

and  Toevs,  A.  L.   1982.   "Single  Factor  Duration  Models  in  a 


Discrete  General  Equilibrium  Framework,"  Journal  of  Finance  37: 
325-338. 

Breeden,  D.  T.   1979.   "Futures  Markets  and  Commodity  Options,"  working 
paper,  University  of  Chicago. 

Chance,  D.  M.   1982.   "An  Immunized-Hedge  Procedure  for  Bond  Futures," 
Journal  of  Futures  Markets,  Vol.  2:   231-242. 

.   1983.   "Floating  Rate  Notes  and  Immunization,"  Journal  of 


Financial  and  Quantitative  Analysis  18  (September):   365-380. 

Cox,  J.  C. ,  Ingersoll,  J.  E.  Jr.,  and  Ross,  S.  A.   1978.   "A  Theory  cf 
the  Term  Structure  of  Interest  Rates,"  Graduate  School  of  Business, 
Stanford  University. 

'.   1979.   "Duration  and  the  Measurement  of  Basic  Risk," 


Journal  of  Business  52:   51-61. 

1981.   "The  Relation  Between  Forward  Prices  and  Futures 


Prices,"  Journal  of  Financial  Economics  9:   321-346. 

Ederington,  L.  H.   1979.   "The  Hedging  Performance  of  the  New  Futures 
Markets,"  Journal  of  Finance  34  (March):   157-170. 

Hicks,  J.  R.   1939.   "Value  and  Capital."   Oxford,  Clarendon  Press. 


-12- 


Hill,  J.  and  Schneeweis,  T.   1980.   "The  Use  of  Interest  Rate  Futures 
in  Corporate  Financing  and  Corporate  Security  Investment,"  pro- 
ceedings of  the  International  Research  Seminar  of  the  Chicago  Board 
of  Trade  (May). 

Ingersoll,  J.  E.   1982.   Discussion  on  "The  Pricing  of  Commodity-Linked 
Bonds,"  by  E.  S.  Schwartz,  Journal  of  Finance  37:   540-541. 

,  Skelton,  J.,  and  Weil,  R.   1978.   "Duration  Forty  Years 


Later,"  Journal  of  Financial  and  Quantitative  Analysis  13 
(November):   627-650. 

Khang,  C.   1979.   "Bond  Immunization  When  Short-term  Interest  Rates 
Fluctuate  More  Than  Long-terra  Rates,"  Journal  of  Financial  and 
Quantitative  Analysis  14:   1085-1090. 

Kolb,  R.  and  Chiang,  R.   1981.   "Improving  Hedging  Performance  Using 
Interest  Rate  Futures,"  Financial  Management  10:   72-79. 

.   1982.   "Duration,  Immunization  and  Hedging  with  Interest 


Rate  Futures,"  Journal  of  Financial  Research  5:   161-168. 

Leibowitz,  M.  L.   1981.   "The  Analysis  of  Value  and  Volatility  in 
Financial  Futures,"  Monograph  of  Solomon  Brothers. 

Little,  P.  K.   1984.   "Negative  Cash  Flows,  Duration  and  Immunization: 
A  Note,"  Journal  of  Finance  39:   283-288. 

Macaulay,  F.  R.   1938.   "Some  Theoretical  Problems  Suggested  by  the 
Movements  of  Interest  Rates,  Bond  Yields  and  Stock  Price  Since 
1856,"  National  Bureau  of  Economic  Research,  New  York. 

Williams,  A.  0.  and  Pfeiger,  P.  E.  1982.  "Estimating  Security  Price 
Risk  Using  Duration  and  Price  Elasticity,"  Journal  of  Finance  37: 
399-412. 


D/206 


Table  1 

Stochastic  Duration  of  Futures  Contracts  on 
Discount  Bonds  and  Coupon  Bonds* 


s-t 
(Year) 

.25 
.25 
.25 

.25 
.25 
.25 
.25 
.25 
.25 
.25 
.25 
.50 
.50 
.50 
.50 
.50 
.50 
.50 
.50 
.50 
.50 
.50 
.50 
.75 
.75 
.75 
.75 
.75 
.75 
.75 
.75 
.75 
.75 
.75 
.75 
1.00 
1.00 
1.00 
1.00 
1.00 
1.00 
1.00 


T-s= 
(Ye 


s=A  | 

aar)        f~ 


0% 


.25 
.50 
.75 
1.00 
1.50 
1.75 
2.00 
5.00 
10.00 
15.00 
20.00 
.25 
.50 
.75 
1.00 
1.25 
1.50 
1.75 
2.00 
5.00 
10.00 
15.00 
20.00 
.25 
.50 
.75 
1.00 
1.25 
1.50 
1.75 
2.00 
5.00 
10.00 
15.00 
20.00 
.25 
.50 
.75 
1.00 
1.25 
1.50 
1.75 


.2072 

.2072 

.4079 

.4058 

.6013 

.5947 

.7866 

.7733 

1.1304 

1.0966 

1.2876 

1.2404 

1.4345 

1.3719 

2.4144 

2.1488 

2.6186 

2.2591 

2.6252 

2.2469 

2.6254 

2.2345 

.1722 

.1722 

.3348 

.3331 

.4872 

.4821 

.6289 

.6189 

.7599 

.7435 

.8799 

.8559 

.9890 

.9566 

1.0875 

1.0459 

1.6541 

1.5167 

1.7512 

1.5752 

1.7542 

1.5689 

1.7543 

1.5623 

.1434 

.1434 

.2761 

.2747 

.3978 

.3938 

.5086 

.5008 

.6088 

.5963 

.6986 

.6808 

.7786 

.7550 

.8495 

.8197 

1.2285 

1.1412 

1.2884 

1.1787 

1.2902 

1.1747 

1.2903 

1.1705 

.1197 

.1197 

.2285 

.2274 

.3267 

.3235 

.4147 

.4086 

.4930 

.4833 

.5622 

.5486 

.6229 

.6051 

Coupon  Rates 


.2072 

.2072 

.4047 

.4037 

.5916 

.5886 

.7671 

.7611 

1.0815 

1.0673 

1.2196 

1.2004 

1.3449 

1.3204 

2.0613 

1.9916 

2.1733 

2.1128 

2.1793 

2.1354 

2.1819 

2.1499 

.1722 

.1722 

.3323 

.3315 

.4797 

.4773 

.6142 

.6097 

.7360 

.7288 

.8451 

.8350 

.9422 

.9289 

1.0278 

1.0112 

1.4688 

1.4296 

1.5299 

1.4971 

1.5331 

1.5094 

1.5345 

1.5173 

.1434 

.1434 

.2740 

.2734 

.3918 

.3900 

.4972 

.4937 

.5906 

.5852 

.6728 

.6652 

.7445 

.7348 

.8067 

.7947 

1.1100 

1.0843 

1.1497 

1.1285 

1.1518 

1.1365 

1.1527 

1.1416 

.1197 

.1197 

.2268 

.2263 

.3219 

.3205 

.4057 

.4029 

.4789 

.4747 

.5424 

.5366 

.5971 

.5897 

Table  1  (cont. ) 


s-t 

T-s=A 
(Year) 

ConDon 

Rates 

(Year) 

0% 

4% 

6% 

H% 

1.00 

2.00 

.6760 

.6538 

.6440 

.6350 

1.00 

5.00 

.9484 

.8875 

.8654 

.8471 

1.00 

10.00 

.9895 

.9138 

.8934 

.8785 

1.00 

15.00 

.9907 

.9110 

.8949 

.8841 

1.00 

20.00 

.9908 

.9080 

.8955 

.8877 

1.25 

.25 

.1000 

.1000 

.1000 

.1000 

1.25 

.50 

.1897 

.1887 

.1883 

.1879 

1.25 

.75 

.2695 

.2669 

.2657 

.2645 

1.25 

1.00 

.3402 

.3353 

.3330 

.3308 

1.25 

1.25 

.4024 

.3948 

.3912 

.3879 

1.25 

1.50 

.4567 

.4461 

.4412 

.4367 

1.25 

1.75 

.5040 

.4901 

.4839 

.4782 

1.25 

2.00 

.5449 

.5278 

.5203 

.5133 

1.25 

5.00 

.7490 

.7042 

.6879 

.6743 

1.25 

10.00 

.7790 

.7236 

.7086 

.6976 

1.25 

15.00 

.7799 

.7216 

.7097 

.7017 

1.25 

20.00 

.7799 

.7194 

.7102 

.7044 

*The  value  of  parameters  used  in  this  table  are  r  =  p  =  5.623%, 


a  -  .00608  and  <  =  .692. 


Table  2 


Stochastic  Duration  of  Futures  Contracts  on  Coupon  Bonds 
When  s-t  is  Extremely  Short  Relative  to  A* 


T-s=A 
(Year) 

Coupon 

Rates 

s-t 

4% 

6% 

8% 

(Year) 

Futures 

CIR 

Futures 

CIR 

Futures 

CIR 

.01 

5 

3.67 

3.81 

3.41 

3.52 

3.23 

3.34 

.01 

10 

4.10 

4.29 

3.79 

3.93 

3.60 

3.73 

.01 

15 

4.05 

4.24 

3.81 

3.95 

3.66 

3.81 

.01 

20 

4.00 

4.18 

3.82 

3.96 

3.71 

3.86 

*Assumed  that  u  =  r  -  5.623%,  a*"  =  .00608  and  <  =  0.692.   The  column, 
CIR  presents  the  stochastic  duration  of  cash  coupon  bonds  with  time  to 
maturity,  A,  which  was  calculated  by  CIR  (1979). 


Table  3 

Stochastic  Duration  of  Futures  Contracts  on 
Discount  Bonds  for  Different  Values  of  < 


s-t 

T-s=A 

(Year) 

(Year) 

<  -  .001 

<  =  .100 

<  =  .692 

.25 

.25 

.2499 

.2437 

.2072 

.25 

.50 

.4997 

.4872 

.4079 

.25 

1.00 

.9990 

.9733 

.7866 

.25 

4.00 

3.9867 

3.8640 

2.2281 

.25 

20.00 

19.5546 

17.3795 

2.6254 

.50 

.25 

.2498 

.2376 

.1722 

.50 

.50 

.4994 

.4747 

.3348 

.50 

1.00 

.9980 

.9473 

.6289 

.50 

4.00 

3.9734 

3.7341 

1.5590 

.50 

20.00 

19.1352 

15.5427 

1.7543 

.75 

.25 

.2497 

.2316 

.1434 

.75 

.50 

.4991 

.4625 

.2761 

.75 

1.00 

.9970 

.9221 

.5086 

.75 

4.00 

3.9602 

3.6099 

1.1684 

.75 

20.00 

18.7390 

14.1363 

1.2903 

1.00 

.25 

.2496 

.2258 

.1197 

1.00 

.50 

.4987 

.4507 

.2285 

1.00 

1.C0 

.9960 

.8977 

.4147 

1.00 

4.00 

3.9471 

3.4911 

.9066 

1.00 

20.00 

18.3639 

13.0022 

.9908 

1.25 

.25 

.2495 

.2201 

.1000 

1.25 

.50 

.4984 

.4391 

.1897 

1.25 

1.00 

.9950 

.8739 

.3402 

1.25 

4.00 

3.9341 

3.3772 

.7184 

1.25 

20.00 

18.0078 

12.0560 

.7799 

HECKMAN       IX 
BINDERY  INC.        |S 

JUN95 

R     a  To  Plc^f  N.  MANCHESTER, 
Bound  -To  -llcasi-    |ND|ANA  46962