Skip to main content

Full text of "Stock market returns and inflation : the effects of economic uncertainty"

See other formats


UNIVERSITY  OF 

ILLINOIS  LIBRARY 

AT  URBANA-CHAMPAIGN 

BOOKSTACKS 


CENTRAL  CIRCULATION  BOOKSTACKS 

The  person  charging  this  material  is  re- 
sponsible for  its  renewal  or  its  return  to 
the  library  from  which  it  was  borrowed 
on  or  before  the  Latest  Date  stamped 
below.  You  may  be  charged  a  minimum 
fee  of  $75.00  for  each  lost  book. 

Theft,   mutilation,   and   underlining   of  books   ore   reasons 
for  disciplinary  action   and  may  result  In  dismissal   from 
the  University. 
TO  RENEW  CALL  TELEPHONE  CENTER,  333-8400 

UNIVERSITY   OF    ILLINOIS    LIBRARY   AT   URBANA-CHAMPAIGN 


1997 
2000 


When  renewing  by  phone,  write  new  due  date  below 
previous  due  date.  t_i62 


120    COPY    2- 

|    »"^ 

■■  <*» — '>>&rj   H       iwJH    ••ft,     Uam    * 
v.  *£:.     */  v      '»!S    i'ls    WW    ' 

-  is5"" 


FACULTY  WORKING 

PAPER  NO,  1120 


Stock  Market  Returns  and  Inflation: 
The  E:ffect3  cf  EEconomic  Uncertainty 


Yoon  Dekko 
Robert  H,  Ede)  stein 


***** 


SS*. 


Coiiegs  p?  Ccnme'se  and  Business  Administration 
Bureau  of  Economic  and  Business  Research 
University  cf  [liin'ois,  Urbane-Champaign 


BEBR 


FACULTY  WORKING  PAPER  NO.  1120 
College  of  Commerce  and  Business  Administration 
University  of  Illinois  at  Urbana-Champaign 
March,  1985 


Stock  Market  Returns  and  Inflation: 
The  Effects  of  Economic  Uncertainty 


Yoon  Dokko,  Assistant  Professor 
Department  of  Finance 

Robert  H.  Edelstein 
University  of  Pennsylvania 


Digitized  by  the  Internet  Archive 

in  2011  with  funding  from 

University  of  Illinois  Urbana-Champaign 


http://www.archive.org/details/stockmarketretur1120dokk 


ABSTRACT 

A    well-documented    but    anomolous    finding    from    the    U.S.    and    other 
stock    markets    is    the    negative   relationship   between    aggregate   stock    returns 
and    inflation.       This    finding    is    contrary    to    traditional    thought    that    non- 
monetary   assets,    such    as    common    stock    (equity),    are   hedges   against   infla- 
tion.      The    empirical     results    of    this    paper    suggest    that    the    market    risk 
premium    for    common    stock    has    increased    over    the    last   three   decades   as   a 
response    to    increased    inflation    uncertainty.       Hence,    the    apparent   contra- 
diction    between    previous    empirical     analyses    and    financial    theory    can    be 
explained    if    one    controls   for    the    degree    of    inflation    uncertainty;      in    that 
case,    the    level    of    inflation,    ceteris    paribus,    does    not   appear   to   affect   the 
expected    real    returns   on   common    stock   equity. 


INTRODUCTION 

A    well-documented    but    anomalous    finding    from    the    U.S.1    and   other2 
stock    markets    is    the    negative   relationship    between    aggregate   stock    returns 
and    inflation.3      This    finding    is    contrary    to    traditional    thought    that   non- 
monetary   assets,    such    as    common    stock    (equity),    are   hedges   against   infla- 
tion.     As   a    result,    over   the    last   several    years,    a    large   quantum   of   academic 
research    energy    has    been    directed    to    the    examination    of   this    issue.      De- 
spite   this   effort,    however,    little   agreement   has   emerged   about   why   and    how 
inflation    affects   stock   prices. 

In    essence,     Malkiel     [1979]    and    Friend    [1982]     independently    suggest' 
that    the    market    risk    premium    for    common    stocks    (hereafter    referred    to   as 
the    risk    premium)    may    have    increased    because    of    increased    inflation    un- 
certainty.4     The   principal   objective  of   this    paper   is    to   examine   this    hypoth- 
esis. 

As    a   first   step,    a   formal    portfolio   theory   model    is   developed    to   explain 
the   inter-relationships   among   the   real    required    returns   on    stock   equity,    real 
asset   returns    uncertainty,    and    inflation    uncertainty.      The   empirical    model    is 
derived    from    the    theory.       In    brief,    the    empirical    findings    from   the   model 
suggest    that:       (i)    the    adverse    impact  of   inflation    uncertainty   on    corporate 
net    operating    income    appears    to    be    the   "principal"    cause   for   the   observed 
increase    in    the    real    required    return    for   common    stocks   over   the   last   three 
decades,    resulting    in    relatively    depressed    stock    prices;     (ii)    the  observed 
negative    relationships    among    expected    inflation    and    subsequently    realized 
stock    returns    are    statistical    artifacts    created    by    a    structural    relationship 
between    the    level    of    inflation    and    the   degree   of   inflation    uncertainty;    (iii) 
the    magnitude    of    the    effect    of    nominal    capital    gain    taxes    on    stock    prices 


(suggested    by,    among    others,     Feldstein    [1980])    is    likely    to    be   overstated; 
and     (iv)    the    lack    of    prior    empirical    support    for    the    nominal    contracting 
hypothesis    apparently    is    the    result  of   ignoring    the   adverse   effect   of   uncer- 
tain   inflation    on    corporate    net    operating     income    (which    tends    to    offset 
capital    gains   on   debt). 

Our    presentation    is    divided    into    four   sections.      Section    I    reviews   the 
previous    literature.       Section    II    develops    the    theoretical    model    to    show   the 
market    equilibrium    relationship    between    the    required    return    for    common 
stocks    and    inflation    uncertainty.       Section    IN    presents    the   data   base,    esti- 
mation    procedures,    and    empirical    findings.       Finally,     implications    of    these 
findings   are   discussed    in   Section    IV. 


I  .       THE    PRIOR    LITERATURE    IN    PERSPECTIVE 

Feldstein    [1980]    and    Summers    [1931],    among    others,    have   attributed 
the    decline    in    real    stock    prices    during    recent    inflationary    periods    to   the 
failure    of    corporate    income    tax    indexation:       firms    which    report    inflation 
generated    book    profits    are    penalized    by    an    increased    tax    burden.       The 
immediate    limitation    of    the    "tax   effect"    hypothesis    is    its    implicit   assumption 
that    corporations    have   no   debt.       Empirical    studies,    ante-dating    the   work   of 
Irving    Fisher,    have   confirmed    that   short   term   nominal    interest   rates    resciond 
"at    most"    point-for-point    to    changes    in    the    inflation    rate.       This    implies, 
because    tax    deductions    are    calculated     for    nominal    interest    payments,     a 
decrease    in    the    burden    of   real    interest   and    principal    payments    to   corpora- 
tions.   Then,    the   real    net   effect  of   inflation   on    taxes   and   debt   is    less   clear. 
Even    without    introducing    debt,    the   tax    gains-depreciation    effect   hypothesis 
may    be    less    important    than    expected    on    a    priori    grounds    because   the   U.S. 
tax    system    permits    the    use    of    counter-inflation    tax    accounting    methods, 
which    implicitly    may    act    as    a    substitute   for   indexation    (Gonedes    [1981]). 5 

in    contrast    to    the    proponents    of   the   tax   effect   hypothesis,    Modigliani 
and    Cohn     [1979]    allege    that    investors    have    systematic    money    illusion;    in- 
vestors   do    not    realize    capital    gains   on    debt,    or   mistakenly   use   the   nominal 
required    rate    of    return    to   discount   the    real    cash    flows,    thereby   explaining 
the    observed    decline    in    stock    prices   during    inflationary    periods.       Because 
there    is    ample    evidence    for    the    "rationality"    of   stock   price   determination, 
most    eccnomists    are    likely    to    reject    the    irrational    behavior    hypothesis; 
particularly    if    the    observed    negative    relationships    between    stock    returns 
and     inflation    could    be    explained    without    the    assumption    of    "irrational" 
behavior.      Nevertheless,    the   theory   of   money    illusion   or   the   irrational 


behavior-    hypothesis    has    a    long    and    even     resoectabie    history,    perhaps 
ante-dating    Keynes    [1936]    who    viewed    the    stock    pnce    as    "the   outcome   of 
mass    psychology   of  a    large   humber  of   ignorant    individuals    (p.    ,54)."   More- 

over,     in    spite   of   numerous    studies    shn.it    t-h«    ^ 

biuaies    about   the    nominal    contracting    hypothesis 

since    the    1950's,     convincing    evidence    has    yet    to    be    presented    for    the 
theoretically    anticipated    wealth    redistribution    effect   of   unexpected    inflation 

among    creditors    and    debtors        Our    finHin^c    h^   ~ 

'       uur    rir>dings   do   explain   why    previous    tests 

for   the   nominal    contracting    hypothesis   may   have   failed. 

Geske    and    Roll     [1983]     present    an    unconventional    view    that    the   nega- 
tive  stock   return-inflation    relationship   is   not  created    by   a   "causative"    effect 
of    inflation    on    stock    prices.       They    argue    that   a   decrease    in    stock    prices, 
in    an    efficient    stock   market,    signals    an    increase    in    the   government's    mone- 
tized   debt    and    its    consequence,    inflation;    and,    thererore,    they   claim    that   a 
"reverse    causality"    from    stock    returns    to    inflation    is    logical.      Or    course, 
some    feedback    effect    from    the    stock   market    to   money    supply    is    plausible.  * 
As    will    be   demonstrated    later    in    this    paper,    the   observed    negative    relation- 
ship   between    expected    inflation   and    subsequent   stock   returns    is   a    statistical 
artifact,    created    by    a    structural    relationsnip    between    the   level    of   inflation 
and    the    degree    of    inflation    uncertainty.       Hence,    Geske   and    Roll's    reverse 
casuality   position    seems    less   than   convincing. 

Malkiel      [1979]     and     Friend     [1982],     working     in     tangentially     related 
subject    areas,    independently    suggest   a   much    more   plausible   explanation    for 
the    observed    negative    relationship    between    stock    returns    and    inflation:' 
they    surmise    that    the    risk    premium    for    common    stocks    has    increased    as   a 
resoonse    to    inflation    uncertainty.       However,    emp,rical    evidence    for    impacts 
of   inflation    uncertainty   on    the   risk   premium    has    yet   to   be   presented. 


II  .       THEORY    AND    MODEL 

11.1.  Portfolio   Choice   under    Uncertain    Price   Changes 
The   economy    is   described   as: 

Assumption    1:     Individuals    (denoted    by   superscript    k)    are   standard    Sharpe- 
Lintner   CAPM    investors. 

Assumption   2:    There    is    only    one    firm    which    issues    two   assets:       (i)    short- 
term    nominally    risk-free    bonds    (denoted    by    subscript    o); 
and    (ii)   common    stock    (denoted    by    subscript   s).         Supply   of 
these   assets    is   fixed. 

Assumption    3:     Real     rates    of    return    and    the    rate    of    price    changes    follow 
continuous-time     stochastic     (Wiener)     processes,     which     are 
time-homogeneous   Markov    processes. 
The    instantaneous    rate    of    the    price    change,3    n,     is    described    by    a 

Wiener   process: 


(1)  ndt  =   E[7t]dt  +  a  y   Jdt 

where    E    is    the    expectation    operator;    a      is    the    standard    deviation    of  the 
Wiener    process    of    price    change,    that    is,    a      represents    inflation    uncer- 
tainty;9   y       is,     by    construction,     a    standardized    normal    random    variable 
which     is    identically    and    independently    distributed    over    time;       E[y    ]    =    0 
and      E[y£]    =   1;      and   dt   is   an    infinitesimal    time   period. 

71 

It    is    further    assumed    that   the   nominal    interest   rate   before    taxes,    R    , 

o 

is    known    at    the    beginning    of    the    period.       Since    taxes    are   calculated    for 
nominal    interest    payments,    the    net    real    interest    rate   after   personal    income 


taxes,    r    .    is   defined    as 
o 


10 


(2) 


r  dt  =   (1-t    )R   dt   -   rcdt   +  cr2dt 
o  p      o  n 


where  t      is   the   personal    income   tax    rate.11 
P 

Changes   in   price  uncertainty   may   cause   a   change   in    the   firm's   produc- 
tion   function,    or    a    shift    in    demand   for   its  output.      Uncertainty   aPcut   the 
future,    induced   Py   uncertainty   about   price  changes,    is   likely   to   change   the 
firm's    investment    decision.       Similarly,    consumers    may    aiter    consumption- 
saving    decisions    because   of    perceived    changes    in    price    uncertainty.       Fi- 
nally,   because    the    asset    return    generating    function   should    be  viewed   as   a 
reduced    form    of   the    production    and   demand   functions,    a   two-factor   return 
generating    process    for    the    firm's    asset    real    return,    r    ,    is   assumed   to   be: 

3 


(3)  r   dt   =    E[r Jdt   +  a   y     'dt   +   b   a  y Jdt 

a  d  3d  a     71     R 


where  a  y      represents    the   stochastic   component   of   the   asset    return    which    is 

3     3 

independent   of  uncertain   price   changes,    that   is      E[y   y    J    =0      by   construe- 

3       /  L 

tion;    and      b      =    cov(r    ,    7x)/a2,    that   is,    b      measures   the  degree  of   respon- 
a  '  a  n  a 

siveness    of    the    real    asset    return    with    respect   to   uncertain    price  changes. 
Given    the    firm's    asset    return   generating    function    (3),    and    the  values 
of    the    firm's    asset    (V),    debt    (D)    and    equity    (S)   at   the   beginning   of  the 
period,    the    real    rate   of    return    on    the    firm's   equity   after   personal    taxes, 
r    ,    can    be  expressed   as    (see   Appendix   A): 


(4) 


rdt=E[r]dt+ay   Jdii   +  b   a  y   %'dt 
s  s  ss  s   n7  n 


where      a      =    (1-t    )(1-t    )a      V/S,       that    is,    a      represents    the    real    rate  of 
s  p  c     a  s 


return     risk    for    ccmmon     stock    which     is    independent    of    uncertain    price 

chanqes;    and    P      measures    the    degree    of    responsiveness    of    the    real    stock 
s 

return    with     respect    to    uncertain     price    changes,    that    is,    cov(r    ,7i)/cr2. 

S  71 

Using    separate    notation    for    personal    capital    gain    tax    rate,    g    ,    and    the 
corporate   capital    gain    tax    rate,    g    ,    b      will    be   (see   Appendix    A): 


(5)  b      =   6    9    b      V/S    +   8      D/S    -6g    V/S    -    g 

v    '  s  pea  p  p3c  ap 


where    0       =    1     -    t    ;       and      6      =    1    -    t    .       Equation    (5)    illustrates    that   b      is 
p  p  c  c  s 

jointly    determined    by    the    relationsnip    between    the    asset    return    and    un- 
certain   price   changes    (b    ),    the   capital    structure,    and    tax    rates. 

3 


1 1  .2.  Portfolio    Equilibrium   Adjustments 

For    any    information    set    about    the   changes    in    the    price    level    and    real 
returns    on    equity   and    bonds,    investors   would    be   expected    to    readjust   their 
asset   portfolios.      The   investor's   objective   is: 


(6)  max    E[U(Wk   +  Wk[r   dt  +  ak(r      -    r    )dt])] 

o  s      s  o 

k 
a 

s 

where    U     is    the    individual's    utility    function;    W       is    the    initial    wealth    of 
investor    k    at    the    beginning    of   the   period;    and   a      is    the    fraction   of   initial 
wealth    invested   in   equity.      The  optimality   condition   becomes:12 


(7)  U'(Wk)      E[(rs    -r    )dt]    + 


U"(Wk)    W      E[{r   dt   +  ak(r      -    r    )dt}    (r      -    r    )dt]    =   0 
o  ss  OS  oJ 


Since      E[r  dt(r      -    r   )    dt]    =  cov(r    ,    r      -   r   )dt  =  -(1    +  b   )  a2,      and 

Los  o  oso  srt 

E[{(r      -    r    )dt}2]    =    var(r      -    r    )dt    =    (a2    +    (1    +    b    )2   a2)dt,      (7)    is   re- 
Lts  o  s  o  s  srt 

arranged    to   be: 


(8)  E[r      -    r    ]    =  ck{-(1    +  b    )   a2   +  ak(a2   +   (1    +  b    )2   a2)} 

v     '  LS  O  l  S  71  SS  S  71 


k  k       k  k 

where    c      =    -U"(W    )W    /U'(W    ),       i.e.,    the   Pratt-Arrow   measure  of   relative 

risk    aversion;     and    dt    is    eliminated    because    it    appears    in    both    sides    of 

k  k         k 

equation    (3).      To    get    the    market    equilibrium    condition,    let     y      =  W    /ZW 

1  II 

and   -A  =   (I   *r-  )      .      Ey   multiplying   both   sides   of  equation    (3)    by   \v    /c    ; 
c 

and   aggregating   over   k: 


(9)  E[r      -    r    }    =   -A(  1  +b    )   a2   +  A{a2   +   (1+b    )2   a2}</ 

s         o  s       7i  s  s         it     : 


where   \    is    viewed    as    the    market    price    of    risk;    and    a      is    the   proportion 
of  total   value  of  common    stocks   to   total    value  of  all    assets. 

In    order    to   facilitate   the  derivation  of  an   empirically    testable   model,    it 
is    subsumed    that    the    net  supply  of  bonds   is   zero,    that  is,    a     =  1.      Then, 
equation    (9)   becomes: 


(10)  E[r     -   r  ]   =  X   {a2   +  (b2   +  b    )   a2} 

s  o  *    s  s  S        Jl 


Equation    (10)    illustrates    that    the    risk    premium    increases    when    a2 

increases   if  b      is    less   than    -1    or  greater   than   0.      Given    the   linear   relation 
s  s 

ship    between    real    stock    returns    and    uncertain    price    changes    in    equation 
(4),    if    b      is    greater    than    zero,    common    stocks    are   not   protected   against 


unexpected    "deflation,"    and,    therefore,    the   risk   premium    increases   when   a2 

increases.      The    risk    premium   decreases   when   a2    increases    if   b      is   between 

/is 

-1  and  0.  The  result  is  not  "bizarre"  because  the  risk  premium  is  ex- 
pressed vis-a-vis  bonds,  and  the  degree  bonds  hedge  against  unexpected 
price  changes,  cov(r  ,7t)/a2,  is  exactly  -1.  It  has  been  well-documented 
empirically  elsewhere  that  b  is  negative;  this  analysis  examines  whether 
the  observed  negative  relationships  among  stock  returns  and  inflation  are 
interrelated  to  the  effect  of  "inflation  uncertainty"  on  the  expected  risk 
premium   for   common   stocks   and,    if   so,    why. 

Since    r      and    r      are    after    personal    income   taxes,    and    pre-tax   aata   is 
so  K 

observed,    the  empirical   moael    is   modified    to   be  equation    (11): 


(11)  E[R      -    R    ]    =     = a2   + (b2   +   b    )  a2 

S  O  1-t  S  1-TS  S  71 

P  P 

=       *,    Of    +    P2    OZ 


where  R  and  R  are  nominal  returns  on  equity  and  bonds,  respectively, 
before  personal  taxes;  and  x  is  the  overall  effective  personal  income  tax 
rate.13'   14 


III.      THE    EMPIRICAL   MODEL 


III  .1 .      Data    Base 


15 


Expected    rates    of    inflation    and    stock    market    returns    are    estimated 
using    the   Livingston   expectations   data,    which    is   perhaps   the   richest  source 
of    ex-ante   information    for  major   economic  variables.      Individual    respondents 
generated   six-month   forward   forecasts    for   rates  of   inflation   and    stock 


10 


returns,     for    each    of    the    semi-annual     surveys.       The    risk    premium    and 

inflation   uncertainty   measures   are  estimated   as   follows: 

(i)       For    each    survey,    the    arithmetic    averages    of   forecasted    stock   returns 
and    inflation    rates,    respectively,    represent    the    market    consensus    of 
expected    stock    market    return    and    expected    inflation    rate.       The   risk 
premium     (PREM)    is    obtained    by    subtracting    the    six-month    Treasury 
bill    rate    (at    the    beginning    of    the    survey    month)    from    the    expected 
stock   market   return. 

(ii)     Since   the  measure  of   inflation   uncertainty,    a2,    is    not   directly  observed, 
three    alternative    surrogates    are    used:       (a)    the    cross-sectional    vari- 
ances   of    individual     forecasted    inflation    rates,    V(LE.n);     1G    (b)    the 
inflation    forecast    errors    from    previous    predictions,     FECPI;17    and    (c) 
expected    inflation    rates,    LE  n.    IS 
Finally,    a2,    the    variance    for    asset    uncertainty,    independent  of   price 

changes,    is    estimated    from    the    variance   of   the  monthly   realized    real    stock 

return    on    the   S&P    500   for   the   six   month    sample   period   prior   to  eacn   of   the 

surveys,    V  (RS).    19 

III. 2.       Inflation    Uncertainty    and    the    Risk    Premium:       Empirical    Findings 

Given    the    data    base    for    the    risk    premium,    inflation    uncertainty   and 
the    variance    of    real    stock    returns,    the  empirical   model   analog    for   equation 
(11),    the    principal    empirical-theoretical    testing    equation,    will    be   equations 
(12): 
(12-a)  PREMt  =  aQ   +  a      V(LE  rt)   +  a2   Vt(RS) 

(12-b)  PREMt   =   aQ   +   a^    FECPI  +   a?    FECPIt_3    +   a3   V^RS) 


(12-c)  PREM,   =   a0   +  a.    LEjt   +  a„   V  (RS) 

to  let 


where    the    subscript   t   represents    "at   the   time  of   the    Livingston    semi-annual 
survey";    PREM   is   the   risk   premium;    V(LE  n)    is    the   cross-secticnal    variance 
of    the    forecasted    inflation    rate;20    FECPI    is    the   forecast   error  of   the   infla- 
tion   prediction    (note    that   only    observed    forecast  errors   at   the   time  of   the 
survey21    are    present    in    (12-b));     LE  n    is    the  expected    inflation    rate;    and 
V  (RS)    is    the    variance    of    monthly    real    stock    return    (for    the    six    month 
sample    period    prior    to    each   of  the   surveys   at   the   time   t)   orthogonalized    to 
the  estimated   unanticipated    inflation    rate. 

The    regression    results    for    equations    (12),    reported    in   Table    1,    show 
that    the    risk    premium    increases    when    inflation    uncertainty    increases.22 
These    results    are  consistent  across    regressions,    and    robust  with    respect   to 
various    measures    of    inflation    uncertainty.      The  coefficients    for   the  various 
measures    of    inflation    uncertainty    are    significantly   positive   even   when   con- 
trolling    for    uncertainty    about    real    activity    (V   (RS)).       This    implies    that 
increased    inflation    uncertainty    has    informational    content    (i.e.,    bad    news) 
for    the   stock   market.      Also,    the  coefficients   of  V  (RS)    are   statistically   sig- 
nificantly   positive    throughout    the   regressions,    which    is   consistent  with   the 
assumption    of   risk  averse   behavior.23      The   positive,    statistically   significant 
coefficients    for    the   inflation   prediction    forecast  errors   variables   are  consis- 
tent   with    the    hypothesis    that    investors    have    adaptive    expectations.       In 
order    to    control    for    the    possibility  of  temporal    trends   in   equations   (12),    a 
time    trend    variable    (TIME:    1950.05    =    0.01,    etc.)    has   been    introduced   into 
the    regressions.    The    regression    results,    after    controlling    for   the   possible 
time  effect,    are  virtually   unchanged. 


Insert   Table   1    here 


12 


Ceteris    paribus,     increasing    risk    over    time    is   created    by   unanticioated 
events,    which    tend    to    depress    stock    prices    ex    post,    and    thereby    lead    to 
lower    ex    post    realized    rates    of    return    for    investors.      Hence,    the   positive 
ex   ante     relationship    between    the    risk    premium    and    inflation    uncertainty 
(i.e.,     results    found    for    equations    12a   and    12b    in    Table    1)    implies    a   nega- 
tive  ex    post    relationship    between    the    realized    stock    return    (RS    )    and    the 
change    in     inflation    uncertainty.       (This    argument    is    expanded    below    in 
Section     1 1 1. 3.)      This    implication    is    confirmed    econometrically    by    the    OLS 
regression,    equation    13: 

(13)  RS     =       0.069      -      0.061    Alog    V(LE  n)    -     0.043   Alcg    V  (RS) 

(4.793)      (-2.121)  (-3.166). 

Adj    R2    =   0.279,    F    =   3.729,    DW    =   2.235    (1950.06-30.06) 

where    RS     is    the   semi-annual    log    realized    real    return   on    the   53>P    500   at   the 
time    of    the    survey;    and      Alog    V(L£  n)    and      Alog    V   (RS)    are   measures    for 
the   change   in    inflation    uncertainty    and    real    activity   uncertainty,    respective- 

iy. 

III. 3.       Expected    Inflation    and    Stock    Returns:       Empirical    Findincs 

The    portfolio    choice    theory,    developed    above,    indicates    that   the   level 
of    expected    inflation,    ceteris    paribus,    should    not   affect   investor's   decision- 
making;   and    thereby    the    risk    premium    should    be   statistically    unrelated    to 
the   level    of   expected    inflation.       If   it   were   plausible   to   assume   that   the    level 
of    expected    inflation    is   a   good    measure   of    (or   highly   correlated   with)    infla- 
tion   uncertainty,    then,    a    positive    emDirical    relationship    between    the    risk 
premium   and   expected    level    of   inflation    mignt  occur.       In   order   to   obtain    the 
"true"    relationship   of   statistical    insignificance   between    the    risk   premium   and 


13 


the    level    of    expected    inflation,    the    analysis    must   control    for   inflation    un- 
certainty. 

Equations    (14),     controlling    for    inflation    and    non-price    stock    market 
uncertainty,    confirm    the    anticipated    results.       Furthermore,    if  one  assumes 
that  a   change   in   the   level   of  expected    inflation    reflects   a   change   in    inflation 
uncertainty,    the    results    contained    in    equations    (14)    explain    why    ex    post 
realized    stock    returns    are    negatively    related    to    changes    in    the    expected 
level   of  inflation. 

(14-a)  PREMt  =   -0.012   -   0.949   LE  n   +  5.906   V(LEtt)    +      5.513   V  (RS) 

(-2.043)    (-1.638)  (2.943)  (2.255) 

Adj    R2   =  0.505,    F   =   14.531,    DW   =   1.336   (1960.06-50.05) 

(14-b)  PR  EM     =      -0.018    -        0.044    LE  n  +     0.935    FECPI     ,, 

(-3.304)      (-0.143)  (2.325) 

+        0.797    FECPI.    -    +   5.373    V  (RS) 
t-3  t 

(2.167)  (2.471) 

Adj    R2   -   0.504,    F   =   11.156,    DW   =    1.774   (1960.06   -   30.06) 

As    demonstated    in   Table    1,    equations    12-c,    there   exists   an   observable 
positive    relationship    between    the    ex    ante   risk   premium   and    the   level   of  ex 
ante    expected    inflation.       The    ex    ante    relation    is    consistent    with    the   ob- 
served   negative    relationship    between    ex   ante   expected    inflation   and    subse- 
quently   (ex    post)    realized    returns.       The    consistency    emanates    from    and 
is    likely    to    be    explained    by    a    "structural"    relationship    between    the   level 
of    inflation    and    the    degree    of    inflation    uncertainty.       The    hypothesized 
structural     relationship    between    the    level    of    inflation    and    the    degree    of 


14 


inflation   uncertainty   can   be   representee   by   equation    (15-a): 
(15-a)  Et7t  =  p(nt)  cj2  ^         p   >   0 

En    is    expected    inflation.      p    is    assumed    to    be    a    monotonically    non- 
decreasing    function    of    the    inflation    level,    once    the    rate   of   inflation   rises 
above    some    threshold     (e.g.,     2-^    percent    according    to    Logue    and    Willet 
[1976]     and    Hafer    and    Heyne-Hafer    [1981]).       In    other    words,    when    the 
inflation    level    is    relatively   high,    the  degree  of   inflation   uncertainty   tends    to 
be    more   clcselv    associated    with    the    inflation    level    and    vice    versa.    Then, 
equation    (15-b)    represents    the    dynamic    relationship    between    the    level    or 
inflation   and   the   degree  of   inflation   uncertainty, 


(15-b)         Et7i  <  pt  if     Etn  >  o 


Etn  >=  pt 


if      E  71  ^  6 


where    a    dot   over    the  variable  denotes   the   rate  of   its   change;    and   5   is   the 
threshold    level    of    expected    inflaticn.       The    relationship    between    inflation 
uncertainty   and   stock   returns   can   be   expressed   as   equation    (15-c). 


(15-c)  RS     =  |   (CJ2        -   CT2  );  4   <    0, 


By    substituting    equation    (15-a)     into    equation    (15-c),    and    factoring    out 
expected   inflation   at   time   t-1,    equation    (15-d)    is   created. 


15 


(15-d)  RSt    =  i    [(Etn   -   pt)/pt]Et-1n 


Given    the    hypothesized    relationship    of  equation    (15-bj,    y     is    likely   to 
be    negative    when    the    inflation    level    is    relatively    high    (i.e.,    above    the 
threshold    level),    and    vice    versa.      This    implies    that    the  magnitude  of  the 
coefficient   of   the   level   of  expected   inflation    in    the   stock   return    regression, 
such   as   equaton    (15-d),    should   be   (given   a   negative  -4)   more   negative  when 
the    inflation    level    is    relatively    low    and    stable.      It   is   also   possible   for   this 
coefficient    to    be    positive    when    the    inflation    level    is    relatively    high    and 
unstable.     In    either    case,     given    the    theory,    the    coefficient   of   expected 
inflation    in    the   stock   return    regression    is   a   statistical    artifact  created   by   a 
structural     relationship    between    the    level    of    inflation    and    the    degree   of 
inflation   uncertainty. 

The    relationships    for  monthly,    quarterly,    and    semi-annual   ex    post   real 
stock    returns    with    the    corresponding    ex    ante    expected    inflation   measures 
(at   the    beginning    of  the   period)   are   examined    in   Table   2.      In   general,    the 
results    suggest  that  the   negative  estimated   coefficient   for  expected   inflation 
disappears    when    the    sample    period    is    characterized   by    relatively   high   and 
unstable   inflation. 


nsert    i  able   2   here 


In    order    to    investigate    the    relationship    between    the  magnitude  of  the 
estimated    coefficient    for    expected    inflation    with    the    level    of   and    the    in- 
stability   of    inflation,    the    value   of    the    estimated    coefficients    (COEF   is   the 


15 


estimated    coefficient    of    the    monthly    Treasury    Bill    rate    for    the   simple   real 
stock    regression,    RS     =   a    +   COEF    *   TB      1)    is    regressed   on    measures   of   the 
level    and    instability    of    inflation.       The    empirical    results    for   these   analyses 
are    shown    as   equations    (16).      The   subscript   J    in    equations    (16)    denote   the 
sample    period24    for    the    stock    return    regression;    AVINF    and    VARINF    are, 
respectively,    the    average    and    the    variance    of    the    percentage   monthly   in- 
flation   rate    for    the    corresponding    sample   period;    and    AVDINF    is    the   aver- 
age   of    the    change    in    the    percentage   monthly    inflation    rate    for   the   corres- 
ponding   sample    period.       These    finding    are    consistent    with    the    results    in 
Table   2   and    lend    support    to   the   position    that   the   observed    negative   relation' 
ships25    between    expected    inflation    and    subsequent    stock    returns   are   statis- 
tical  artifacts. 

(16-a)  COEF,    =      -17.523    +   781.392    AVINF,    +     13.050    VARINF, 

(-7.331)         (3.442)  (1.636) 

Adj    R2    =   0.333,       F    =   7.495 

(16-b)  COEFj    =    "20.203   +   19.633   AVDINFJ 

(-6.961)      (2.562) 
Adj    R2    =   0.176,      F    =   6.562 

IV.       IMPLICATIONS    AND    CONCLUSIONS 

This    paper    has    demonstrated    that   the    risk   premium    for   common    stocks 
increases    when    inflation    uncertainty   increases,    and   common    stocks    are   not, 
even    vis-a-vis    bonds,     hedges    against    uncertain    inflation.       This    finding 
contrasts    with    a    belief    by    some    economists    that   bond    investment   is    riskier 


17 


with    respect  to   inflation   than   equity   investment.26 

In    Section    II,    b      is    expressed    as      6    9b      V/S   +  9    D/S    -   9    g    V/S    - 

s  r  pea  p  pJc 

g    .       For    simplicity,    it    was    assumed    that    the    net    supply    of  debt   is   zero. 

Then,    b      equals      99b      -   6    g      -    g    .       The   positive   relationship   between 
'       s      ^  pea  pac        ap  K 

the    risk    premium    and    inflation    uncertainty    implies   that   b      is   less   than    -1  , 
and    thereby    b      (the    degree   of    responsiveness    of    before    tax    profits   with 

3 

respect  to   unexpected    inflation)    is   less   than    (-1    +  9    g      +  g    )/9    9    .      There- 
K  r  p3c        3p        p   c 

fore,    if  nominal   capital   gains   are   completely   taxed    (g~   =   t     and   g    =   t    ),    b 

is    also    less   than    -1.      In   the  other  extreme  case   where   nominal    capital   gains 

are  not  taxed   at  all    (g     =  g      =  0),    b      is   less   than    -1/9    9     or   -2.67   (assum- 

c  p  a  p   c 

ing   that  9      =  0.75   and   9      =   0.5). 
y  p  c 

These    results    imply    that    b      must    be   sufficiently   negative,    regardless 
of  a   nominal    capital   gain   tax,    if    the    risk    premium   is   positively   related   with 
inflation    uncertainty.       In    other    words,     the    adverse    effect   of    uncertain 
inflation    on    before   tax    profits    is    likely    to    be    a    principal    cause    for    the 
depressant    effect    of    inflation    on    stock    prices.27      This    finding    contrasts 
with     Feldstein's     [1981]     argument    that    an    important    depressant   effect   of 
inflation    on    share    prices    results    from    nominal    capital    gain    taxes    and    the 
"historic    cost"    methods    of  depreciation;    not   particularly   from   the  decline   in 
before    tax    profits.       Therefore,    this    paper's    findings    indicate    that    prior 
claims    about    the    importance    of  the   tax   system   for  determining   stock  values 
(relative  to   uncertain    inflation   effects)    may   have   been   overstated. 

The    adverse    effect   on    before    tax    profits   will    be   intensified   if  debt   is 
present    because    it  is   "piled   upon"   the   smaller  equity   base.      Therefore,    the 
findings    may    explain    why    previous    tests    for    the    nominal    contracting    hy- 
pothesis   have    failed    to    show    the  wealth    redistribution   effect  of  unexpected 
inflation    between    bondholders    and    shareholders.       In    particular,     share- 


13 


holders'    capital    gains    on    debt   are   likely    to    be   offset   by    this   adverse   effect 
on    before    tax    profits,    because   inflation    uncertainty    increases    the   "business 
risk"    and    thereby    the    "financial    risk"    as    the   debt-to-equity    ratio    increases 
(Modigliani    and   Miller    [1963]).       In   other   words,    inflation    uncertainty    implies 
an    increase    of    "non-diversifiable"    risk,    which    increases    with    the   debt-to- 
equity    ratio. 

The    economic    implication    of    uncertainty    about    the    future    has    been 
discussed    long    before    by    a   classical    work   of    Frank    Knight    [1921],    and    the 
adverse    effect    of    inflation    uncertainty    on    economic    activity    has    been    rec- 
ognized   in   macroeconomic   studies    (for   example,    Lucas    [1973],    Barro    [1976], 
Friedman    [1977],    and    Cukierman    and   Wachtel    [1979],    among   others).      This 
adverse    effect    on    real    activity    is    perhaps    best    summarized    by    Friedman's 
Nobel    Laureate    Lecture:      Greater   inflation    uncertainty    shortens   the   average 
duration    of    contracts    and    reduces    the    efficiency    of    the    price    system    in 
allocating    resources,    resulting    in    the   lower   growth    rate   of   real    output   and    a 
potential    increase   in   the   unemployment   rate.      The   price   system   becomes    less 
efficient    because    "the   harder   it   becomes    to   extract   the   signal    about   relative 
prices    from    the    absolute   prices"    (p.    467),    the   greater    inflation    uncertainty 
is. 

Friedman's    argument    is    weil    supported    by    Vining    and    Elwertowski's 
[1976]    empirical    work    about    the    behavior    of    changes    in    individual    prices 
and    general    inflation.28      They    found    that    high    inflation    tends    to    be    as- 
sociated   with    a    greater    dispersion    of  changes    in    relative   prices,    that   is,    a 
structural    relationship   exists    between    the    instability   of   general    inflation    and 
the    dispersion    of    relative    price    changes.       Uncertainty    about    the    future, 
associated    with    higher    general    inflation,    arises    from   unpredictable   changes 
in    the    relative   price   structure;    ana,    consequently,    a   higher    risk   premium    is 


19 


required    for    an    investment    project   when    the   general    inflation    rate    is    high. 

As  would  be  expected  from  this  paper's  results,  a  recent  survey  of 
non-financial  corporations  listed  on  New  York  Stock  Exchange,  conducted 
by  Blume,  Friend  and  Westerfield  [1931],  found  that  inflation  is  considered 
to  be  one  of  the  key  factors  depressing  real  plant  and  equipment  expen- 
ditures; and  the  corporations  attributed  this  adverse  effect  to  increased 
uncertainty  of  sales,  prices,  wages,  and  the  cost  of  financing  as  a  con- 
sequence of   inflation. 

Finally,  the  findings  indicate  that  the  "irrationai  behavior"  hypothesis 
cannot  be  supported.  High  inflation  is  associated  with  relatively  low  stock 
prices  simply  because  risk  averse  investors  require  a  higher  discount  rate 
adjusted   for   greater   uncertainty   about   the   future. 


TABLE    1.       EQUATIONS    12* 

RELATIONSHIPS     BETWEEN     THE     RISK     PREMIUM     AND     INFLATION 
UNCERTAINTY,    JUNE    1930   THROUGH    JUNE    1980 


Equation    12-a          PREMt  =  cQ   +  Cj    V(LE  7t)    +  c^V  (RS)    +  c.   TIME 

Eq.                                     C-  c2                      c  Adj    R2            F                     DW 

12-a-1*                          4.242  --                      --  0.331           20.277          1.681 
(4.503) 

12-a-2                           2.852  6.642                 --  0.430          19.497          1.765 

(3.205)  (2.768) 

12-a-3                           4.428  5.691               -0.693  0.502          14.450          1.376 

(3.402)  (2.351)           (-1.630) 

Equation   12-b         PR  EM.    =  cn   +  C-FECPL    ,   +  c-FECPI,    -    +  c,V,(RS)    +  c,TIMEt 

t  U              I                   t~c             c.  L"  i             S      I                          4               l 

Eq.                                      c.  c0                      c,  c                 Adj    R2       F                 DW 


c1 

co 

1.304 
(3.904) 

0.974 
(2.361) 

12-b-1                             1.304  0.974  --                 --               0.450      17.377      1.337 

(3.904)  (2.361) 

12-D-2                           0.908  0.775  5.862            --              0.517      15.272     1.776 

(2.588)  (2.356)  (2.501) 

12-Q-3                           0.944  0.305  5.362          -0.009        0.505      11.200     1.730 

(2.534)  (2.323)  (2.470)      (-0.317) 

Equation   12-c         PREMt  =  cQ   +  c      LE  n   +  c_Vt(RS)   +  c^  TIMEj. 

Eq.                                      C1  c2  c3                   Adj    R2            F                     DW 

12-C-1*                         0.950  --  --                   0.127            6.656          1.665 
(2.530) 

12-C-2                           0.542  8.902  —                   0.405          14.599          1.745 

(2.032)  (3.732) 

12-C-3                            1.706  7.663  -0.131            0.433          11.408          1.946 

(2.461)  (3.211)  (-1.310) 


t   t-statistics   are   in   parentheses   below   the   estimated   coefficients. 

Ecuaticns    followed    by    *    indicate    that    the    regression    is   adjusted    for   first- 
order   autocorrelation    (usina   the   Cochrane-Orcutt  method). 


TABLE   2.       THE    RELATIONSHIP    BETWEEN 
EXPECTED    INFLATION    AND    SUBSEQUENT    STOCK    RETURNS 

RSt   =   c0   +   c   E       „t 


Eq 


Period 


(t-stat)     Adj    R2       Eq 


Period 


(t-stat)     Adi    R2 


Panel    A. 

(RS6t  = 

C0   +  C1LEt-lV 

- 

1.    55.I-65. 

II 

-18.57 

(-2.30)        0.17 

4. 

55 . 

I-73. I  I 

-6. 

25 

(-2.63) 

0.14 

2.    66.I-73. 

II 

-5 .  75 

(-0.86)      -0.02 

5 . 

66. 

I-80.I 

0. 

Pi  1 
u  i 

(    0.37) 

-0.03 

3.    74.I-80. 

1 

3.68 

{    0.73)      -0.04 

6. 

55 . 

I-80.I 

-1  . 

75 

(-1.42) 

0.02 

Panel    B. 

.  (RS6t  = 

C0   +   C1TB6t-1} 

1.    59.1-65. 

II 

-7.22 

(-0.33)      -0.02 

4. 

59. 

I-73. il 

-5 

3  ~> 

(-2.30) 

0.13 

2.    66.1-73. 

II 

-6.39 

(-1.41)        0.06 

5 . 

66. 

I-80.I 

-0 

—  n 
.  /  o 

(-0.33) 

-0.03 

3.    74.1-80. 

1 

0.37 

(    0.11)      -0.09 

6. 

59. 

I-80.I 

-1 

.99 

(-1.28) 

0.02 

Note:       The    six-month    Treasury    bill    has    been    available    since    January    1959. 


Panel    C. 

1.  55. 1-65. IV 

2.  66. 1-73. IV 

3.  74. 1-80. IV 


(RS3t  =  c0  *  ClTB3t-1) 

-11.22      (-2.36)        0.10 

4. 

55. 

1-73. IV 

-6.09      (-3.02) 

0.10 

-5.52     (-1.23)        0.02 

5. 

66. 

1-80. IV 

0.62      (   0.28) 

-0.02 

1.82      (   0.52)      -0.03 

6. 

55. 

1-80. IV 

-1.72      (-1.27) 

0.01 

Panel    P. 

1.  55.01-65.12 

2.  66.01-73.12 

3.  74.01-80.12 


(RS1t  =  c0   +  ClTB1t-1) 


•11.55      (-2.54)        0.04 

-7.12      (-1.73)        0.02 

1.40      (    0.45)      -0.01 


4.  55.01-73.12    -6.39      (-3.43)        0.04 

5.  65.01-80.12     0.02      (    0.01)      -0.01 

6.  55.01-80.12   -2.07      (-1.67)        0.01 


RSS    =  #-month    real    return   on   the   S&P   500. 

TBit    =  tt-month   Treasury-bill    rate. 

LEtt    =  six-month    Livingston   expected   inflation    rate. 


to 

cc 

UJ 

Q 

_i 

O 

X 

III 

< 

or 

X 

< 

Q 

co 

Z 

LU 

O 

Q. 

\- 

n 

< 

<; 

X 
c/) 
< 

u 


c 

o 

<J 

c 

^J 

in 

o 

U 

j_, 

c 

<D 

C 

4-j 

aj 

<- 

cj 

ai 

03 

E 

a 

> 

a 

03 

OS 

a 

■4—1 

~03 

l/l 

r 

a; 

s_ 

C 

a; 

O 

'  r- 

Z 

— 

+       a: 


CM 


in 

c 

03 


a 

03 

U 


> 


<\j 


10 

03 
X 

03 


—  0) 


.a 

n 

03 

a 

X 

s_ 

03 

O 

h 

U 

> 

c 

cj 
en 


CM 


in 

X 
i 
CO 


o 

a> 

fej 

"O 

o 

0) 

c 

o 

T3 

cj 

O 

c 

c 

o> 

75 

c 

c 

0) 

',_. 

f— 

o 

o 

^- 

r- 

X 

O 

03 

■  — 

h- 

"o 

(U 

3 

— 

cr 

< 

_i 

> 


LO 


> 

+ 


CO 


0) 

o 

03 
CO 

o 


CO 


CD 


o 


a 

03 

u 


o 
in 

'_ 
03 

c 


1)        — 

JO  > 

03  > 

X 

1*0 


Q 

c 
i 
c 

a: 
c 

c 


> 


LO  O 


03 

n 

CO 

CO 

K 

0) 

+ 

i 

— i 

> 

> 

c 

~ 

u 

c 

C3 

o 

1 

Q 

> 

<1 

(_ 

c 


CO 


00 


C"> 


o 

c 

_    £  r 

03         -J        — 


> 
II 

Q 


u  C 


ai 


X      v     u      c 


o 


03 

a 


a 

o 

u 

■/I 

CJ 

!/) 

0) 

.  N 

<U 

f 

03 

— 

•  "* 

«-j 

03 

~ 

^0 

> 

CO 

i03 

03 

~^ 

^ 

^ 

o 

ii 

X 

Q 

03 

X 

c 

CO 

w 

03 

o 

.  _ 

ii 

c 

c 

in 

03 

> 

OJ 

r- 

x 

o 

<Z 

5 

.03 

■  ■« 

G) 

*^ 

w 

<J) 

"oj 

01 

r- 

03 

1_ 

03 

■  — 

.— 

!_ 

c 

a 

•  — 

<— 

a 

c 

03 

a 

o 

'•- 

U 

03 

03 

o 

CJ 

03 

-O 

03 

0) 

-w 

.Q 

*J 

"oj 

03 

03 

■03 

r~ 

03 

'U 

o 

5 

t_ 

o 

</> 

.03 

-^ 

p" 

OJ 

—- 

_j 

o 

5 

w 

03 

03 

u 

a 

03        il 

'•— 

_» 

II 

ii 

03 

Q 

1            « 

*-■ 

"ai 

u 

c 

z 

•  Z 

TJ 

C3 

o 

20 


FOOTNOTES 


1.  This    finding    has    been    well    documented    by    a   number  of   studies   since 
the    mid-1970's:       Lintner    [1975],    Bodie    [1976],    Jaffe    and    Mandelker 
[1976],     Nelson     [1976],     Fama    and    Schwert     [1977],    and    Friend    and 
Hasbrouck    [1982],    among  others. 

2.  For  examples,    see   Gultekin    [1983]    and    Solnik    [1983]. 

3.  The    negative    relationship    can    be    described    in    three    different    ways: 
realized    aggregate    stock    market    returns    are    negatively    related    to   (i) 
expected    inflation    (at    the    beginning    of  the   time   period);    (ii)   changes 
in    the    expected    inflation    rate    (during    the    time    period);    and    (iii) 
lagged   and   contemporaneous   unexpected    inflation    rates. 

4.  Pindyck  [1984]  examines  a  closely  related  issue  about  stock  market 
share  valuation,  and  finds  that  inflationary  uncertainty  is  likely  to 
have   led   to  depressed    real    share   prices. 

5.  In    addition,    fewer    firms    than    might   have   been   expected   have  actively 
changed   from    FIFO   to    LIFO.      This   suggests    that   the   tax   cost  associated 
with   the   FIFO   method    is   probably   insignificant   relative   to   the   inventory 
management    cost    under    LIFO    method    (see,    Granof  and   Short    [1984]). 
Also,    note   that   the   U.S.    tax    laws   do   not  allow   the   use  of  different   in- 
ventory  valuation   methods   for   financial    and   tax   purposes. 

6.  For    example,     Rogaiski    and    Vinso     [1977]     showed    a    "bi-directional" 
causality   between   stock   returns   and   money   supply. 

7.  The    adverse    impacts    of    inflation    uncertainty  on    real    economic   activity 
have   been   well    recognized   in    several    macroeconomic   studies;      see   Lucas 
[1973],     Barro     [1976],     Friedman    [1977],    and    Cukierman    and    Wachtei 
[1979],    among  others. 

8.  Inflation    is    assumed    to    be    neutral    to    avoid    the   intricacies  of   relative 
price  changes   in   the  model   derivation. 

9.  Uncertainty    about    inflation    can    be    viewed    as    a  dispersion   measure  of 
the    distribution    from    which    a    point    forecast    (expected    inflation)    is 
drawn.      Knight    [1921]    made   a  distinction   between    risk   and   uncertainty. 
Risk   occurs    when    the    future    is    unknown,    but  the   probability  distri- 
bution   of    future    states    is    known.      Uncertainty  occurs   when    the   prob- 
ability    distribution    is    itself    unknown.       However,     modern    portfolio 
theory    draws    no    distinction    between    the    two    concepts.    Risk   and   un- 
certainty  are   used    interchangeably   in   this   study. 

10.  The    stochastic    continuous-time    version    of    the    Fisher    equation    was 
orginally   derived   by    Fischer    [1975]. 

11.  The    personal    income    tax    rate   across   individuals   is   assumed    to   be   con- 
stant. 


12.  The    marginal    utility    of    end-of-period   wealth,    the   first-order  condition 
for   (6),    is   expanded    in   a   Taylor   series   about   initial    wealth. 

13.  Note   that   r     and    r     are  after   personal    taxes.      Since   taxes   are   Daid    for 

so  r 

nominal    returns,      E[r    |    =    E[(1    -    i    )R      -   n]      and      E[r    I    = 

s  p      s  o 

E[(l   -   tp)Ro  -  n]. 

14.  Equation    (11)    may    be    transformed   into   the   "generalized"    Fisher  equa- 
tion  for   stock   returns   by   solving    for    E[R    ]    as   the   dependent  variable. 

The    difficulty    with    the    empirical   test  for   the  generalized    Fisher  equa- 
tion   would    be    that    the    real    interest    rate    and    the    inflation    level   are 
likely    to    be    intercorrelated    (for    example,     see-Mundell     (1963)    and 
Sargent    (1972));    and,    therefore,    the   Fisher   equation    for   stock   returns 
should    be    treated    as    a    pseudo-reduced    form    of    a    set    of    structural 
equations    in    a   macroeconcmic   model    (Levi   and   Makin    [1973]).      For   this 
reason   the   current  analysis   examines   the   impact  of   inflation   uncertainty 
on    the    risk    premium    rather    than    the    required    return    for    common 
stocks . 

15.  Details  about  the  data  base  and  estimation  procedures  can  be  obtained 
by  contacting   the  authors. 

16.  Cukierman    and    Wachtel     [1979]    present    formal    proof    that    the    cress- 
sectional    variance    measure    is    closely   related   with    inflation   uncertaintv 
within    a    rational   expectations   model;    and    Bomberger  and    Frazer    [1931  | 
present    empirical    evidence    that   the    Livingston   cross-sectional   variance 
is   an    internally   consistent  measure  of  inflation   uncertainty. 

17.  When  prior  forecast  errors  are  realized  (ex  post),  it  seems  intuitively 
appealing  that  ceteris  paribus  the  future  should  appear  relatively  more 
uncertain . 

18.  There    appears    to    exist    a    structural    relationship    between   the   level   of 
inflation    and   the  degree  of  inflation   uncertainty.      See   Logue  and  Willet 
[1976],    Jaffe    and    Kleiman     [1977],     Cukierman    and    Wachtel     [1979], 
Taylor     [1981],     Fischer     [1981],     Frohman,     Laney    and    Willet    [1981], 
Hafer     and     Heyne-Hafer     [1981],     Pagan,     Hall    and    Trivedi     [1983], 
Holland    [1984]    and    Pindyck    [1984].       For    the   survey  of  most  of  these 
studies,    see    Holland.       The    current    study    finds    a    higher   correlation 
between    expected    inflation    and    the    cross-sectional    variance    of    the 
forecasted   inflation    rate   for  the   post-1966   period. 

19.  V(RS)  is  computed  from  monthly  realized  real  stock  returns  which  are 
orthogonalized  to  the  estimated  monthly  unexpected  inflation  rates  be- 
cause   the    risk    of    common    stock,    y  a   ,    in   equation    (4)    is   independent 

of  uncertain   inflation,    v  a    .  s   S 

7  n  n 

20.  Since      V(LE  n)      is    a    relatively    small    number,    it    has    been    scaled   by- 
multiplying   by   100. 


22 


21.  Let    the    subscript    t-1 ,     for    example,     represent    the    December    1980 
survey.       FECPI      -    is    defined    as    the    difference    between    the    realized 
inflation    rate    from    the    beginning    of    January    1981    to   the  end   of  June 
1981    and    the    expected    inflation    rate    for    the    corresponding   period   at 
the   December  1980   survey.      It   should    be   noted   that   this   forecast  error 
was    not    observed    when    the    June    1981    survey    (represented    by    the 
subscript    t)    was    conducted    in    early    June    or    late    May    of    that  year. 

22.  Evidence    of    the    rationality    and    the    infomational    efficiency    in    the 
Livingston    survey    data    for    the    post-1960    period    (Brown    and    Maital 
[1981])    indicates    a    potential    structural    break    in    the    Livingston    data 
around    1960.       Therefore,     the    regression    results    for    equations    (12) 
were    separated    into    two    sub-periods:    (i)   June   1960   to  June   1980;    and 
(ii)   June   1955   to  June   1980.      Since   there   is   no  qualitative  difference   in 
the    results    for    these    two    sub-periods,    only   the"  results   for   the   post- 
1960   period   are   reported   to   save   space. 

23.  The    magnitude   of   the    coefficient  estimate  of   V(RS)   can    be   interpreted 
as    the    market    price  of   the   risk.      Note   that   the  estimate  of   the  market 
price    of    risk    is    quite    stable    across    the    regressions,    which   indicates 
the   robustness  of  the   empirical   model. 

24.  The    first    sample    period    is    1950.01-54.12,    the    second    one    is    1951.01 
-55.12,...,    the   last  one   is    1976.01-80.12:    that   is,    27   regression   coeffi- 
cients  were  obtained. 

25.  Geske    and    Roll    suggest    [1983]    a   "reverse  causality"    argument.      They 
hypothesize    that    changes    in    the    risk    premium    are    probably    inconse- 
quential   in   explaining   observed   negative   relationships   between   expected 
inflation    and    subsequent    stock    returns.      They   further   argue   that  the 
large    negative    coefficient    of    expected    inflation    in    the    stock    return 
regression    (estimated    from    an    earlier    sample    period    by    Fama    and 
Schwert    [1977])    "cannot   be  taken   seriously   as   a   causative  value,    since 
a    rise    in   the  Treasury-bill    rate  of  only   five   percent    .  .  .    [would   imply] 
negative    expected    stock    returns    (p.     9)."       Hence,    they    surmise    a 
reverse    causal    relationship,    and   suggest  that  decreases   in   stock   prices 
cause    inflation    through    monetization    of    governmental   debt.      However, 
their    hypothesis    is   inconsistent  with   the  empirical    results   presented    in 
Table    2;      in    particular,    their    analysis    cannot    account    for    either  the 
changes    in    coefficient    magnitudes    or  changes   in   coefficient  signs  over 
time.      The    "statistical    artifact"    argument   seems   to   be   a   more   plausible 
explanation . 

26.  For  example,    an   earlier  work   by   Gordon   and    Halpern    [1976]    claims   that 
"an    increase    in    the    uncertainty    of    the    inflation    will    result    in    a    re- 
duction   of    the    expected    risk   premium"    (p.    563).      However,    they   con- 
sidered   the    effect  of   inflation    uncertainty  only  on   the   required    rate  of 
return    for    bonds,    and    their    argument    is    a    tautological    result  of  the 
assumption    that    real    returns    on    non-monetary    assets   are   independent 
of  inflation. 

27.  This    result    has    been    reported    independently    by    Pindyck    [1984]    in   a 
related    but   different  context.      He   also  claims   that  the  decline   in   stock 
prices    is    attributed    to    an    increase   in    uncertainty  of   the   "gross"   mar- 
ginal   return   on   captiai    (i.e.,    before   tax   profits). 

23.      See,    also,    Parks    [1978]. 


REFERENCES 


Barro,    R.J.,    1976.      "Rational    Expectations   and    the   Role  of  Monetary 
Policy,"    Journal    of   Monetary    Economics,    January,    pp.    1-32. 

Blume,    M.E.,    Friend,    I.,    and   Westerfield,    R.,    1981.      Impediments   to 

Capital    Formation,      The      Rodney     L.     White     Center,     University     of 
Pennsylvania. 

Bodie,    Z.,    1976.      "Common   Stocks   as   a   Hedge   against    Inflation,"    Journal   of 
Finance   31,    May,    pp.    459-70. 

Bomberger,    W.A.     and    Frazer,    F.J.,    1931.       "Interest    Rates,    Uncertainty 
and    the    Livingston    Data,"    Journal   of    Finance    36,    June,    pp.    561-75. 

Brown,  F.B.  and  Maital,  S.,  1931.  "What  Do  Economists  Know?  An  Em- 
pirical Study  of  Experts'  Expectations,"  Econometrica  49,  March,  pp. 
491-504. 

Carlson,  J. A.,  1977.  "A  Study"  of  Price  Forecasts,"  Annals  of  Economics 
and    Social    Measurement,    June,    pp.    27-52. 

Cukierman,    A.    and    Wachtel,    P. A.,    1979.    "Differential    Inflationary    Expecta- 
tions   and    Variability    of    the     Rate    of     Inflation,"    American    Economic 
Review   69,    September,    pp.    595-609. 

Darby,    M.R.,    1975.       "The    Financial   and   Tax    Effects   of  Monetary    Policy   on 
Interest   Rates,"    Economic    Inquiry    13,    pp.    266-76. 

Dokko,    Y.      1984.      "Effects   of   Unexpected    Inflation   on   Wealth    Re- 
distribution   and    Stock    Prices:      Test   of   the   Nominal    Contacting    Hypo- 
thesis."     BEBR    Faculty    Working    Paper,    WP    November.      University   of 
Illinois   at   Urbana-Champaign . 

Fama,     E.F.,    1975.       "Short-term    Interest    Rates   as   Predictors   of   Inflation," 
American    Economic    Review   65,    June   pp.    269-82. 

and    Schwert,     W.G.,     1977.       "Asset    Returns    and    Inflation," 


Journal    of    Financial    Economics   5,    November,    pp.    115-46. 

Feldstein,    M.,    1976.      "Inflation,    Income   taxes,    and   the   Rate  of   Interest:      A 
Theoretical    Analysis,"    American    Economic    Review    65,    December,    pp. 
809-20. 

,     1980.       "Inflation    and    the    Stock    Market,"    American    Economic 


Review   70,    Decemoer,    pp.    339-47. 
,    and    Summers,     L.,    1979.      "Inflation   and   the   Taxation   of   Capital 


Income    in    the    Corporate    Sector,"    National    Tax   Journal    32,    December, 
pp.    445-70. 


24 


Fischer,     S.,    1975.       "The    Demand    for    Index    Bonds,"      Journal   of   Political 
Economy   83,    June,    pp.    509-34. 

,    1981.      "Towards   an    Understanding   of  the   Costs   of    Inflation:    II," 


in  K.  Brunner  and  A.  Meltzer  ed .  ,  The  Costs  and  Consequence  of 
Inflation ,  Carnegie-Rochester  Series  on  PuPlic  Policy,  Autumn,  pp. 
5-41. 

Friedman,    M.,    1977.      "Nobel    Lecture:      Inflation   and    Unemployment," 
Journal    of   Political    Economy   35,    pp,    451-72. 

Friend,  I.,  1982.  "Effect  of  Inflation  on  Saving,  Investment,  and  Capital 
Markets,"  in  M.  Blume,  J.  Crockett  and  P.  Taubman,  ed.,  Economic 
Activity   and    Finance.      Cambridge:      Ballinger   Co. 

and    Blume,    M.E.,    1975.      "The    Demand    for    Risky   Assets," 


American    Economic    Review   65,    December,    pp.    900-22. 
and    Hasbrouck,    J.,    1932.      "Effect  of    Inflation   on   the   Profitability 


and    Valuation    of    U.S.    Corporations,"    in    M.    Sarnat    and    G.P.    Szego 
ed .  ,  Saving,    Investment,    and    Capital    Markets    in    an    Inflationary 

Economy.      Camondge:      Ballinger  Co. 

and    ,    1982.      "Comments  on    Inflation   and   Stock  Market, 


American    Economic    Review    72,    March,    pp. 
,     Landskroner,    Y.,    and    Losq,    E.,    1976.      "The   Demand    for   Risky 


Assets    under    Uncertain    Inflation,"      Journal   of   Finance    31,    December, 
pp.    1287-97. 

Frohman,    A.,    Laney,    L.O.,    and    Willet,    T.D.,    1981.       "Uncertainty    Costs 
of    High    Inflation,"    Voice  of  the    Federal    Reserve   Bank   of   Dallas,    July, 
pp.    1-9. 

Geske,     R.    and    Roll,     R.,    1983.      "The   Fiscal   and   Monetary    Linkage   between 
Stock    Returns    and    Inflation,"   Journal   of   Finance   38,    March,    pp.    1-30. 

Gonedes,    N.,    1981.       "Evidence   on    the    Tax    Effects    of    Inflation   under   Hi- 
storical   Cost    Accounting    Methods,"   Journal  of   Business   54,    April,    pp. 
227-70. 

Gordon,  M.J.  and  Halpern,  P.  I.,  1976.  "Bond  Yield  Spreads  Under  Un- 
anticipated Inflation,"  American  Economic  Review  66,  September,  pp. 
559-65. 

Granof,  M.H.  and  Short,  D.G.,  1934.  "Why  Do  Companies  Reject  LIFO?" 
Journal    of   Accounting,    Auditing   and    Financing    7,    Summer,    pp. 

Gultekin,     B.N.,     1983.       "Stock.  Market    Returns    and    Inflation:       Evidence 
from   ether  Countries,"    Journal   of   Finance  38,    March,    pp.    49-65. 

Hafer,     R.W.    and    Heyne-Hafer,    G.,    1981.      "The   Relationship   between    Infla- 
tion   and     Its    Variability:       International     Evidence    from    the    1970's," 
Journal   of  Macroeconomics,    Fall,    pp.    571-77. 


25 


Holland,    S.A.,    1934.      "Does    High    Inflation    Lead   to   More   Uncertain    Inflation?" 
Federal    Reserve    Bank   of   St.    Louis    Review,       February,      pp.       15-25. 

Jaffe,    D.    and    Kleiman,    E.,    1977.      "The  Welfare    Implication   of   Uneven 

Inflation,"    in    Lundberg   ed .  ,    Inflation   Theory   and    Anti-inflation   Policy, 
Westview   Press,    pp.    285-307. 

Jaffe,    J.F.    and   Mandelker,    G.,    1976.      "The    Fisher    Effect   for   Risky   Assets: 
An    Empirical    Investigation,"    Journal   of    Finance    31,    May,    pp.    447-58. 

Keynes,      J.M.,      1936.        The   General    Theory   of    Employment,    Interest,    and 
Money .      London:      Macmillan. 

Knight,     F.J.,    1921.      Risk,    Uncertainty   and    Profit,    Reprinted   1967,    Boston: 
Houghton   Mifflin   Co. 

Levi,    M.D.    and   Makin,    H.,    1973.      "Anticipated    Inflation   and    Interest   Rates: 
Further    Interpretation    of    Findings    on    the    Fisher    Equation,"    American 
Economic    Review   68,    DecemPer,    pp.    801-12. 

Lintner,    J.    1975.,    "Inflation   and   Security    Returns,"   Journal   of   Finance   30, 
May,    pp.    259-80. 

Logue,    D.E.    and    Willet,    T.D.,    1976.      "A    Note  on    the   Relation   between    the 
Rate  and   Variability  of    Inflation,"    Economica ,    May,    pp.    151-58. 

Lucas,    R.E.,    1973.      "Some    International    Evidence  on   Output-Inflation   Trade- 
offs,"   American    Economic   Review   63,    December,    pp.    721-54. 

Malkiel,    B.,    1979.       "The    Capital    Formation    Problem   in    the   United   States," 
Journal   of   Finance   39,    May,    pp.    291-306. 

Modigliani,     F.    and   Cohn,    R.A.,    1979.      "Inflation    Rational    Valuation   and   the 
Market,"    Financial    Analyst  Journal,    March/April,    pp.    3-23. 

and    Miller,    M.H.,    1963.      "Corporate    Income  Taxes   and   the  Cost 


of    Capital:      A    Correction,"    American    Economic    Review    53,    June,    pp. 
433-43. 

Mundell,     R.A.,     1963.       "Inflation    and     Real    Interest,"    Journal   of   Political 
Economy   71,    June,    pp.    280-83. 

Nelson,    C.R.,    1976.       "Inflation    and    Rates    of    Return    on   Common   Stocks," 
Journal   of   Finance   31,    March,    pp.    471-83. 

Pagan,    A.R.,    Hall,    A.D.,    and    Trivedi,    P.K.,    1983.      "Assessing    the   Var- 
iability of   Inflation,"    Review  of   Economic   Studies,    OctoDer,    pp.    535-96 

Parks,     R.W.,    1978.       "Inflation    and    Relative    Price    Variability,"    Journal   of 
Political    Economy   86,    February,    pp.    79-95. 

Pindyck,    R.S.,    1984.       "Risk,     Inflation,    and   the   Stock   Market,"      American 
Economic    Review    74,    June,    pp.    335-351. 


26 


Rogalski,     R.J.    and   Vinso,    J.D.,    1977.      "Stock    Returns,    Money   Supply   and 
the    Direction    of    Causality,"    Journal    of   Finance    32,    September,    pp. 
1017-30. 

Sargent,    T.J.,    1972.       "Anticipated    Inflation    and    the    Nominal    Rate   of    In- 
terest,"  Quarterly   Journal   of   Economics   86,    May,    pp.    212-25. 

Solnik,    B.,    1983.       "The   Relationship   Between   Stock   Prices   and    Inflationary 
Expectations:       The     Internatioal     Evidence,"     Journal   of   Finance     38, 
March,    pp.    35-48. 

Summers,    L.H.,    1981.       "Inflation   and   the   Valuation   of  Corporate   Equities," 
Working    Paper,    National    Bureau  of   Economic   Research. 

Taylor,    J.B.,    1981.       "On    the    Relation    Between   the  "Variability  of   Inflation 
and    Average    Inflation     Rate,"     in     K.     Brunner    and    A.    Meltzer    ed .  , 
The   Cost  and   Consequence  of    Inflation,    Carnegie-Rochester  Conference 
Series   on    Public   Series,    Autumn,    pp.    5-41. 

Vining,     D.R.     and     Elwertowski,     T.C.,     1976.     "The    Relationship    between 
Relative     Prices     and     the     General     Price    Level,"     American    Economic 
Review   66,    September,    pp.    609-708. 


HECKMAN 

BINDERY  INC. 


JUN95 

»>d.To-Plcas#  N.MANCHESTER 
INDIANA  46962     '