Skip to main content

Full text of "Sustainable financing for protected areas: a comparison of parastatal and state-funded conservation agencies in Africa and the Caribbean"

See other formats


5 AN l448¢ Koprints WANG 


Sustainable Financing for Protected Areas: A Comparison of 
Parastatal and State-Funded Conservation Agencies in Africa and 
the Caribbean 


Alexander N. James, Sam Kanyamibwa, and Michael J. B. Green 


Conference paper prepared for: 
"The Economics and Politics of Park Management" 
Political Economy Research Center 
Bozeman, Montana, USA 


October, 1996 


1. Introduction 


Increasing the funding for conservation activities is a perennial issue in protected area management. 
Though data is scarce, there can be little question that most of the protected areas in the world are 
under-funded. Where reported, protected area agency budgets in the developing countries average 
only one third the level required to achieve their stated conservation objectives (James et al/., 1997). 
Examples of "paper parks", or government gazetted protected areas that have no administration or 
budget, are common in many parts of the world (IUCN, 1992; IUCN, 1994). As one study noted, 
"Budget constraints make it unlikely that a system will receive enough funding from the central 
government to effectively manage all protected areas" (Dixon and Sherman, 1990: 78). Thus, the 
chronically insufficient funding of protected areas contributes in no small part to the continuing threats 
to global biodiversity. 


An alternative to the dependence on governments for conservation funding is offered by parastatal 
protected area agencies. A parastatal protected area agency is a semi-autonomous organization that 
receives a yearly grant from government, but also has the right to raise and retain its own revenues. 
Parastatals often take advantage of their greater financial independence by diversifying their sources 
of revenue beyond the collection of park fees and the provision of visitor services. Other sources of 
funds tapped by parastatals include investment and trust fund income, subscriptions and donations, 
and foreign assistance. Parastatal agencies typically pay no dividends or taxes, so surplus revenues 
from operations can be reallocated to conservation activities within the protected areas. 
Governmental control over parastatals is exercised through protected area legislation and by 
representation on a board of directors, which often includes a broad range of stakeholders. 


Institutional theory provides a framework for analyzing the performance of protected area agencies. 
Institutional theory states that the incentives governing environmental performance, at any level, stem 
from three national characteristics: the formal or written laws (and property rights), the social 
conventions and constraints, and the level of enforcement of each. The interaction of the formal 
structures with the social codes of behavior create an institutional environment, which provides the set 
of incentives. When the formal laws, policies and programs are supported by the social expectations 
and conventions, and both receive adequate enforcement, an institutional incentive is created (UNEP, 
1996: Presber-James, 1996; North, 1990). A parastatal agency is an example of the 
institutionalization of a new incentive structure for the management of national parks and protected 
areas, which depends upon both a formal change in the agency_s legal designation, and an informal 
change in the attitudes and strategies of the agency managers. 


The difference in formal institutions between government and parastatal protected area agencies is 
embodied in the structure of property rights over the park revenues. A property right is the claim on 
the benefit stream arising from an asset, and which is enforceable over other individuals and 
organizations through a set of property rules (Bromley, 1992). In the case of a parastatal, the control 
over the stream of revenue arising from the operations of a protected area is a property right that has 
been transferred from the government to the conservation agency. The property right over protected 
area revenue creates the incentive to optimize the value of the benefit stream from the protected area 
assets. Optimization of the benefit stream requires that the managers of the parastatal agency 
maximize the revenues flowing from the protected areas subject to the constraint of maintaining 
adequate conservation of the biodiversity resources. This constraint is enforced formally through 
government regulation and oversight of the protected areas, and informally through the stewardship 
ethic of the park managers. 


Thus, the creation of a parastatal protected area agency can be expected to result in a range of 
outcomes, depending upon the response of protected area managers to the institutional incentives. 
An improvement in financial performance can not be taken as a given once the property rights to the 
protected area revenues have been transferred to the agency. This modification of property rights is 
strictly a formal measure; its success in improving the financial performance depends upon the 
support of the informal rules and modes of operation within the conservation agency. Thus, this study 
will attempt to determine if, in practice, the creation of parastatal protected area agencies has resulted 
in better financial performance than comparable government funded conservation agencies. Whether 
or not financial performance translates into improved conservation results is not easily measured, and 


remains outside of the scope of this analysis. 
2. Methods 


2.1 Data: A number of parastatal protected area agencies were identified in an ongoing project on 
national budgets for protected areas, conducted by the World Conservation Monitoring Centre (James 
et al., 1997). These parastatal agencies, and a control group of government funded agencies, were 
sent a survey questionnaire requesting information on protected area funding. The survey 
questionnaire, reproduced in Annex 1, asked respondents for data on their annual budgets, including 
the total amount of funds allocated to protected areas, the sources of funds, and a self-assessment of 
the adequacy of funds relative to the agency_s stated conservation objectives. A total of 23 parastatal 
agencies and 29 government agencies, located in 30 countries, were contacted. Annex 2 contains a 
list of the surveyed countries and agencies. 


Response to the survey was incomplete, but not out of line with previous WCMC experience in 
collecting data on protected area budgets. Completed questionnaires were received from eight out of 
the 30 countries contacted. Six parastatals provided detailed budgets along with comments on their 
financial activities. Four of the responding parastatals were located in the Caribbean region, and two 
in Africa. Due to the low survey turn-out, the data were supplemented with information on protected 
area budgets from other sources, primarily from previous WCMC protected area surveys (James et 
al., 1997). As a result of the limitations on data, the study compares the financial performance of 
protected area agencies in the Caribbean and Sub-Saharan African regions only. 


Financial performance is measured as the agency_s annual protected areas budget expressed on a 
per square kilometer (PSK) basis. Foreign funds have been excluded from the agency budgets 
because of incomplete and inconsistent data. However, the analysis does note where foreign 
assistance is known to have been significant. The agency budgets include both operating expenditure 
and capital expenditure. However, few countries reported significant capital expenditures, so the 
comparisons are, in practice, reflective of annual operating expenses. The protected area budgets, 
which pertain to a range of years in the mid 1990s, have been standardized to 1996 US dollars. The 
budgets have been converted to US dollars in the budget year reported by the agency, then scaled up 
to 1996 values with the US dollar deflator. The foreign exchange conversion rates and the US dollar 
deflator were taken from IMF (1997). 


2.2 Basis of comparison: The Caribbean and Sub-Saharan African regions are treated separately 
in the analysis. Within these regions, account is taken of the fact that economic development and 
protected area size have a significant influence over conservation budgets (James et a/., 1997). 
Higher income countries can and do invest more in protected area conservation. Secondly, there 
exists a significant economy of scale in protected area management. Small protected areas are 
relatively expensive to administer because of high fixed costs and a large perimeter to area ratio. As a 
result, budgets for small protected areas can appear to be extremely high when expressed on a per 
square kilometer basis. ; 


To remove these effects, parastatal and government agencies from groups of similar countries are 
compared. Each region is divided into three groups of similar countries. These smaller groups of 
comparable countries are selected based on their 1994 per capita income (PCI) as reported by the 
World Bank (1996), and mean protected area size as reported in the survey responses or internal 
WCMC sources. 


In the Caribbean region. protected area agencies are grouped based primarily on mean protected area 
size. The mean area protected by the agencies in the Caribbean sample varies by four orders of 
magnitude, from 0.3 square kilometers to 504 square kilometers. As a result, the Caribbean region is 
divided into the following size classes: (i) mean area over 100 square kilometers; (ii) mean area from 
10 to 100 square kilometers; (iii) mean area less than 10 square kilometers. 


In the Sub-Saharan African region, both protected area size and economic development determine the 
groups of comparable countries. The countries are divided as follows: (i) medium sized protected 
areas. medium level of economic development; (ii) large areas, low level of development; (ili) large 


areas, high level of development. The designations are relative to the African scale of development 
and geography. Thus, large protected area size refers toa mean area of over 2000 square 
kilometers, and higher level of development is above $500 in per capita income. 


3. Results 


3.1 Caribbean: The results for the Caribbean region are summarized in Table 1. On average, the 
parastatal protected areas in the Caribbean receive twice as much funding, $1886 PSK, as the 
government funded protected areas, $989 PSK. In two out of the three comparative groups, the 
parastatals exhibit higher PSK funding intensity than their government Wepleloe counterparts. In all of 
the groups, the parastatals have more diverse funding sources. 


The large size class has only two agencies for comparison: the Bahamas National Trust, a parastatal, 
and the Directorate of National Parks in the Dominican Republic, a government funded agency. The 
parastatal agency invested $324 PSK, compared to $73 PSK by the government agency. The results 
should be viewed in light of the fact that the government funded agency has larger protected areas 
(504 vs. 209 square kilometer mean), and a lower per capita income ($1330 vs. $11 800), both of 
which tend to lower per square kilometer conservation budgets. 


In the medium size class, the parastatal agencies are represented by two independently operated 
protected area systems on separate islands of the Netherlands Antilles, Bonaire and Saba. Five 
government protected area systems are included for comparison: Turks and Caicos, Dominica, 
Jamaica, Trinidad and Tobago, and St. Kitts and Nevis. The control group countries have a mean per 
capita income of $3568, compared to $8956 in the parastatal. The mean area of the government 
funded agencies is 29 square kilometers, compared to 18 square kilometers for the two parastatals. 


In medium sized group, the parastatal administered protected areas received $10 828 PSK on 
average, compared to $619 PSK in the government funded agencies. The parastatal agencies would 
be expected to have higher PSK budgets, due to their higher income levels and smaller mean areas, 
though these differences are not great enough to explain the parastatals_ seventeen times higher rate 
of investment. Among the government funded agencies, the highest budget is recorded for St. Kitts 
and Nevis at $4441 PSK, still well below the parastatals_ budgets. Notably, St. Kitts and Nevis is also 
the most comparable government agency to the parastatals, in terms of mean size and income. 


The small size class is the only group where the government agency reports higher protected area 
investment than the parastatals. In the small size class, the average budget of four parastatal agency 
budgets is $48 059 PSK, compared to $90 157 PSK for the government parks department in Bermuda. 
Bermuda is a highly developed country with a per capita income of $17 790, and has a highly 
fragmented system of small parks (111 protected areas averaging 1 square kilometer each). Unlike 
Bermuda, the parastatal countries have not attained developed country status, as their mean per 
capita income is $5090. Also, the parastatal agencies each have a larger mean area under protection, 
with the exception of St. Lucia. Hence, protected area investment in the parastatal agencies is biased 
downward by their protected area size and per capita income. 


Perhaps the most comparable parastatal agency to Bermuda in terms of mean area is the St. Lucia 
National Trust, which operates 3 protected areas totaling 0.33 square kilometers. The St. Lucia 
National Trust_s protected area expenditures total $560 752 (equivalent to $1.68 million PSK), well in 
excess of the government budget in Bermuda. The three other parastatals in the small size class 
have smaller budgets than Bermuda, but only one fell short by a major amount. The parastatals 
include Antigua ($40 123 PSK), Barbados ($50 120 PSK), and Montserrat ($5220 PSK). 


3.2 Sub-Saharan Africa: Table 2 presents the results for Sub-Saharan Africa. In African protected 
area systems, parastatal investment averages $556 PSK, compared to $38 PSK in government 
funded agencies. In each of the three comparative groups, the parastatals demonstrated both higher 
investment and more diverse funding sources. 


In category (i), the Kenya Wildlife Service, a parastatal, is compared to Uganda, Zambia, and Malawi. 
These are roughly middle income countries with middle sized protected areas. The average per capita 


income in the control group is $237, compared to $250 in Kenya. The mean protected area size 
administered by the Kenya Wildlife Service is 839 square kilometers, while the comparable 
government funded systems have an average area of 1424 square kilometers. 


Kenya_s internally generated budget of $310 PSK is more than ten times greater than that of the 
control group, whose average investment is $29 PSK. In addition to the internally generated funds, 
foreign assistance to the Kenyan Wildlife Service contributes another $160 PSK in operating funds and 
a massive $739 PSK in capital investment, for a total budget of $1209 PSK. Kenya_s total investment 
is very nearly equal to that of South Africa, a considerably more developed country with the highest 
protected areas budget in Africa. 


In category (ii), Tanzania_s parastatal agency is compared to the government agencies in Ethiopia, 
Sudan and Zaire. This group of countries is characterized by their very large protected areas and low 
level of economic development. Per capita income in Tanzania is $140, compared to $100 in Ethiopia; 
per capita income in Sudan and Zaire are not reported. Mean protected area size is 3358 square 
kilometers in Tanzania and averages 5025 square kilometers in the three government funded 
countries. 


The Tanzania National Parks budget is $170 PSK, compared to an average of only $16 PSK for the 
group of government funded agencies. Tanzania National Parks derives almost all of its budget from 
tourism revenues. Donations amount to the equivalent of $3 PSK annually, and the agency receives 
no subsidy from the government. Instead the Tanzanian parastatal remits 50% of its annual surplus to 
the national treasury as a corporation tax. 


In category (iil), the National Parks Board of South Africa and Zimbabwe_s Department of Wildlife and 
National Parks, both parastatals, are compared to the government funded conservation agencies in 
Botswana and Namibia. The parastatal agencies reported an average protected areas budget of $923 
PSK, compared to $67 PSK in the government funded areas. 


The cost of protected area management may be a little lower in the government control group, but 
their higher levels of income imply a greater availability of funds for conservation. Botswana (PCI 
$2800) and Namibia (PCI $1970) are both high income countries by African standards, suggesting 
greater means for government conservation investment. The parastatal countries, South Africa 
($3040) and Zimbabwe ($500), actually have a lower average per capita income than the Botswana 
and Namibia. In terms of mean areas, the protected areas in Botswana and Namibia are larger and 
located in areas of less population density than in South Africa and Zimbabwe, implying lower funding 
requirements. These offsetting factors suggest roughly similar government and parastatal 
conservation budgets; instead, the parastatals_ PSK investment rate is fifteen times higher. 


5. Discussion 


5.1 Caribbean: Diversification of revenue sources has enabled the higher parastatal funding of 
protected areas in the Caribbean region. The incentive created by revenue retention within the 
agencies has led to efforts to develop new sources of funds. These efforts have taken the form of 
more and better services on offer, and new charges for formerly free services. All of these efforts 
represent a greater realization of the economic value of a country_s environmental assets, and the 
reinvestment of these values into conservation activities. The high volume of tourism to the Caribbean 
raises the marketable values of the protected areas, and the parastatal agencies appear to be well 
positioned to take advantage of this financial opportunity. This section briefly reviews the steps taken 
by the Caribbean parastatal agencies to increase and diversify their revenues. 


The parastatal agency in the large size class, the Bahamas National Trust, receives only $11 PSK 
from the government. By comparison, this allocation is only a fraction of the $73 PSK received by the 
Dominican Republic_s parks agency. The Bahamas National Trust adds another $313 to their 
conservation budget from revenues raised and retained in park operations. Subscriptions and 
donations also contribute a small amount. 


In the medium size class, the parastatal agencies on the islands of Bonaire and Saba in the 


Netherlands Antilles are largely independently financed protected areas. Bonaire receives 3% of its 
annual budget from the government, and Saba receives nothing. Both earn the majority of their 
revenues from visitor fees, primarily from diving fees and boat moorings. Both actively seek donations 
from visitors, and manage trust funds which make yearly contributions of interest income. In Bonaire, 
donations contributed $104 PSK, and the trust fund income added $398 PSK, Saba received the 
equivalent of $805 PSK in donations and $186 PSK in investment interest. Though contributing only a 
small proportion of the budgets in Bonaire and Saba, donations and trust fund income alone amount to 
a funding base roughly equivalent to the control group budgets ($619 PSK). 


Further, both Bonaire and Saba are actively taking steps to increase their revenues from visitor 
services, their main source of funding. For example, Bonaire has proposed to the government that 
their diver fee be extended to cover all users of the marine park, including the yachters, windsurfers 
and snorkerlers who currently pay nothing. Additionally, they plan to begin charging a yearly fee to the 
owners of private and commercial moorings in the park. Saba, unlike Bonaire, earns a significant 
proportion of its yearly budget from souvenir sales (equivalent to 23% of operating funds), and plans to 
expand such sales. In both cases, the incentives provided by financial independence have resulted in 
the diversification of revenue sources and a greater capture of the financial value of their 
environmental assets. 


Also in the medium size class is the Department of Environmental and Coastal Resources (DECR) of 
the Turks and Caicos islands, a British dependency. The DECR is a government funded agency 
struggling for greater financial independence. The government funded budget is only $225 PSK, 
considerably below the $619 PSK average for medium sized government conservation agencies in the 
Caribbean. The DECR estimates that their current budget allows them to meet less than half of their 
stated conservation objectives. In response, the agency has taken steps to increase their self- 
sufficiency, but notes that "At least ten proposals regarding self-financing in protected areas have 
been unsuccessfully presented to the government" (Garland, 1997). To provide extra funding for 
protected areas, the DECR has proposed implementing a diving fee, boat license fees, and an 
increase the hotel accommodations tax. To date, only the boat license fees have been approved by 
government, but the revenues must be returned to the treasury. The agency notes that the 
government greatly opposes the "ring fencing” of park revenues, which they perceive as government 
funds. 


In the small size class, St. Lucia is the only one of four parastatals that reported a larger budget than 
Bermuda_s parks department. The St. Lucia National Trust budget is comprised in nearly equal parts 
government grant and internally generated revenues; donations and subscriptions add only 1% to 
total budget. On the basis of revenues raised internally, the St. Lucia National Trust spends nearly 
$750 000 PSK on protected areas, well in excess of the level of funding in Bermuda. 


The other parastatals in the small size class have each taken steps to raise their revenue bases. For 
example, the Antigua National Parks authority has developed a marketing plan "in order to sensitize 
and attract more visitors to the parks" (Martin, 1997). Antigua has recently upgraded its services to 
attract more visitors, and has introduced an all inclusive fee to the parks. In Barbados, fees for use of 
the protected areas have traditionally not been charged. However, the parastatal management 
currently has a proposal for the implementation of user fees before the government. This proposal 
would enable the Barbados National Conservation Commission to reduce its current dependence on 
government funds for about 90% of its budget. 


5.2: Sub-Saharan Africa: Tourism revenues make a major contribution to the conservation budgets 
of the African parastatal agencies. Much of the funding advantage the parastatals have over their 
government funded counterparts stems from the retention of revenue from visitor services and park 
entry fees. Here again, the incentive created by revenue retention appears to lead agencies to 
increase and diversify their funding sources. The African experience with parastatals shows that 
developing countries with substantial tourism can realize a greater proportion of the economic value of 
protected areas through the creation of parastatal agencies. 


In category (i), the Kenya Wildlife Service has positioned itself well to benefit from the country_s large 
share of the region_s tourism, much of which is attracted to the wildlife parks. The agency has 


successfully increased revenues through raising entry fees, improving the visitor services, and 
successfully promoting and marketing the parks. The parastatal has also been extremely effective in 
attracting foreign donors, as noted. Kenya is one of the best examples of successful institutional 
change, as the improved financial performance has been a direct result of the creation of the 
parastatal structure to manage the nation_s protected area system. 


By contrast, Zambia has modified the institutional structure of protected area resource management in 
a different direction. The Luangwa Integrated Resource Development Project (LIRDP) oversees the 
sustainable use of the wildlife resources around the country_s most visited national parks in the 
Luangwa valley. In addition, a sustainable use projects within nearby Game Management Areas have 
been initiated. The projects_ objective is to achieve the sustainable utilization of wildlife in the region 
through transferring some of the property rights over the wildlife resources to the local communities 
(Lungu, 1990). The LIRDP receives a substantial amount of foreign assistance from both bi-lateral 
and NGO donors. Some of the revenues of the LIRDP are passed on to the national parks in the area. 
In 1993, support from LIRDP added $41 PSK to the budget of South Luangwa National Park and an 
adjacent game management area (Dublin et a/., 1995). As a sustainable use project, LIRDP may help 
to reduce the poaching problem in the parks, but is unlikely ever to produce the revenues needed to 
achieve adequate protected area conservation. 


In category (ii), Tanzania, like Kenya, receives a large amount of the East African wildlife tourism. 
However, its internally generated revenues are 50% less than the Kenya Wildlife Service. As a result, 
the achievement of conservation objectives, such as the contro! of poaching, is dependent upon 
foreign funding to a greater extent in Tanzania than in Kenya (e.g. Dublin et a/., 1995). The shortfall in 
its financial performance relative to Kenya suggests that the institutional incentives in Tanzania 
National Parks may not be fully taken advantage of. This may relate to the informal institutions within 
the agency, such as a reluctance to raise park entry fees or to change other modes of operation. It is 
not possible to determine the reasons for the weaker financial performance without closer study, as 
informal institutions are subtle and not easily quantified. 


In category (iii), the South Africa National Parks Board_s high level of financial resources is the result 
of a diversified revenue base. The annual government allocation to the parastatal is equivalent to 
$312 PSK, only about 10% of the total budget. The National Parks Board takes a proactive approach 
to revenue generation, by developing visitor services (68% of budget), generating investment income 
(8% of budget), and soliciting donations (1% of budget). The Board is currently seeking $100 million in 
financial assistance from foreign and domestic sources to expand the country_s network of protected 
areas. 


The incentives provided by financial independence are also driving greater efficiency in the National 
Parks Board_s operations. The agency management notes that certain "commercial operations which 
have been performed in house are being (or will be) outsourced to professional companies" 
(Fearnhead, 1997). If a contractor can perform an operation more efficiently than the Board, then 
outsourcing the operation will reduce the agency_s total costs. The reduction in the Board_s 
operating costs increases the surplus available to fund conservation activities. Thus, the South Africa 
National Parks Board appears to be another example, along with Kenya, of a successful response to 
the incentives created by financial independence. 


The Zimbabwe Department of National Parks and Wildlife Management (DNPWM) has recently been 
converted into a parastatal agency. Their internally generated budget of $302 PSK is similar to that of 
Kenya. Of this amount the government contribution is equivalent to $134 PSK, and foreign assistance 
adds another $92 PSK, for a total annual expenditure of $528 PSK. Before the parastatal structure 
was created in Zimbabwe, the DNPWM had a budget of $144 PSK (Martin, 1993). Since the change, 
government support for protected areas in Zimbabwe has remained roughly constant, but the new 
infusion of funds from protected area operations has resulted in a tripling of the conservation budget. 
The management of the DNPWM notes that they are now "reviewing tariffs so that they are consistent 
with those on the market. Ours were much lower" (Machena, 1997). The agency is also taking steps 
to increase the range of services offered to visitors. 


6. Summary and Conclusion 


The results of this study suggest an asymmetry in the value of park revenues to protected area 
agencies and their value to national treasuries. The revenues arising from protected areas are quite 
small relative to national government budgets, but can be very large relative to protected area 
budgets. The parastatal agencies reviewed here show that the retention of protected area revenues 
makes an enormous contribution to conservation budgets. Further, this study has shown that control 
over the revenue stream creates an incentive to increase revenue generation and diversification, 
thereby maximizing the financial value of a country_s protected areas. Conversely, government 
management of protected areas may fall short of fully realizing the potential financial values because 
of the insignificance of park revenues to the national treasury. Due to this asymmetry of values, a 
parastatal protected area agency can achieve major conservation benefits at little cost to 
governments. 


The parastatal structure creates an "institutional incentive" to improve the financial performance of 
national protected area agencies. For such an institutional change to produce better results, however, 
the informal modes of operation with the agency must be compatible with the new incentives. This 
requires a willingness on the part of agency managers to take the steps necessary to raise revenues, 
reduce costs, and attract foreign support, while keeping biodiversity conservation as the primary 
objective. Not all agencies will have such conducive informal institutions. For example, the Tanzanian 
parastatal appears not to take full advantage of the opportunities provided by financial independence, 
and this may be a reflection of organizational expectations and traditions. On the other hand, Kenya_s 
experience shows that the creation of the parastatal agency can bring about a change in institutional 
behavior, as evidenced by the vigorous measures taken to improve both financial and conservation 
performance. The balance of the evidence presented in this study suggests that the creation of 
parastatal agencies does appear to improve financial performance. 


An important variable not explicitly quantified in the analysis is tourism expenditure. Many countries in 
the Caribbean and Sub-Saharan Africa receive a substantial amount of foreign tourism, and it is 
probably not a coincidence that many of these countries also manage their protected areas through 
parastatal agencies. The quantity of tourism to a country can create a large financial advantage over 
relatively less visited countries, which may distort the analysis presented here. However, it may still 
be true that a parastatal is better positioned to maximize the revenues received from tourism services, 
due to the incentive provided by financial independence. It remains an open question as to how much 
better a given country might do in attracting tourism if they turned their protected areas over to a 
parastatal agency. However, in a country that receives a substantial amount of foreign tourism, a 
parastatal structure is unlikely to hurt financial performance. The outcome depends upon the extent to 
which the protected area managers take advantage of the incentives. 


Tourism expenditure is usually distributed evenly among a country_s protected area system. 
Inevitably, in any country, some protected areas are more marketable than others. Conversely, some 
protected areas may be valuable as reserves for biodiversity conservation, but not attractive to 
tourists. Hence, there is a case for treating the funding and management of national protected area 
networks as a single operating unit and redistributing funds among protected areas. A redistribution of 
funds can take place within a parastatal agency, if it had a mix of financially attractive and non- 
revenue earning protected areas under its authority. Alternatively, a parastatal might manage the 
most marketable areas in a country, and redistribute some of its surplus to government managed 
areas. Either way, the pooling and redistribution of funds in an equitable manner should be a stated 
objective of parastatal agencies in order to further a country_s biodiversity conservation objectives. 


Finally, there is the possibility that the implementation of a parastatal protected area agency could be 
harmful for protected area conservation. The danger lies in the possibility that governments might 
abandon their responsibility for biodiversity conservation after creating a financially independent 
conservation agency. For example, in Tanzania, the government contributes nothing to the parastatal 
protected area budget. Not all protected areas will be able to achieve financial self-sufficiency, and it 
is questionable whether Tanzania has done so. It seems likely that a large proportion of the world_s 
protected areas will not be able to attract enough tourism, or other sources of funds, to ensure 
consistent and adequate conservation budgets. There is public good aspect to much of the global 
protected area system, due to the non-excludability and non-rival nature of the benefits of biodiversity 


(Swanson, 1992). For this reason, governments should not turn to the parastatal structure to remove 
their financial responsibility for environmental protection. Parastatal agencies may best be 
implemented where the marketable values of the protected areas are high enough to ensure long term 


financial viability. 


The authors would like to acknowledge the generous support of the Political Economy Research 
Center in the preparation of this report. 


REFERENCES 


Bromiey, D. (1991) Environment and Economy: Private Rights and Public Policy. Cambridge, MA: 
Basil Blackwell. 


Dixon, J. A. and Sherman, P. B. (1990) The Economics of Protected Areas: A New Look at Benefits 
and Costs. Washington: Island Press. 


Dublin, H. T., Milliken, T. and Barnes, R. F. W. (1995) Four Years After the CITES Ban: Illegal Killing 
of Elephants, Ivory Trade and Stockpiles. |UCN Species Survival Commission African Elephant 
Specialist Group. Gland, Switzerland: IUCN. 


Fearnhead, P. (1997) Response to Questionnaire on Investments in Protected Areas from the National 
Parks Board, South Africa. Cambridge: World Conservation Monitoring Centre (in litt.) 


Garland, J. L. (1997) Response to Questionnaire on Investments in Protected Areas from Department 
of Environmental and Coastal Resources, Turks and Caicos Islands, British West Indies. Cambridge: 
World Conservation Monitoring Centre (in litt.) 


IMF (1997) International Financial Statistics. Washington: International Monetary Fund. 


IUCN (1992) Protected Areas of the World: A Review of National Systems. Volume 3, ice 
Gland, Switz.: IUCN. 


IUCN (1994) Protecting Nature: Regional Reviews of Protected Areas (J. A. McNeeley, J. Harrison, 
and P. Dingwall, eds.). Gland, Switz. and Cambridge, UK: IUCN (World Conservation Union). 


James, A. N., Green, M. J. B. and Paine, J. R. (1997) Financial Indicators for Biodiversity 
Conservation: A Global Analysis of Protected Area Investment. Cambridge, UK: World Conservation 
Monitoring Centre (in press). 


Lungu, F. (1990) Luangwa Integrated Rural Development Project (LIRDP) and Administrative Design 
for Game Management Areas (AMADE)" in Living With Wildlife: Wildlife Resource Management with 
Local Participation in Africa (A. Kiss, ed.). World Bank Technical Paper No. 130. Washington, DC: 
World Bank. 


Machena, C. (1997) Response to Questionnaire on Investments in Protected Areas from the 
Department of National Parks and Wildlife Management, Zimbabwe. Cambridge: World Conservation 
Monitoring Centre (in /itt.) 


Martin, R. B. (1993) "Should Wildlife Pay Its Way?" (Keith Roby address, Department of National 
Parks and Wildlife, Perth, Australia, December 8, 1993) cited in Stephen R: Edwards, "Conserving 
Biodiversity; Resources for Our Future” in The True State of the Planet (R. Bailey, ed.). New York: 
The Free Press. 


Martin, A. M. (1997) Response to Questionnaire on Investments in Protected Areas from National 
Parks Authority, Antigua. Cambridge: World Conservation Monitoring Centre (in litt.) 


North, D. (1990) /nstitutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance. Cambridge: 
. Cambridge University Press. 


Presber-James, S. (1996) "An Institutional Approach to Incentives for Conservation." Paper presented 
at the IUCN World Conservation Congress, Montreal, Quebec, 17 October. 


Swanson, T. M. (1992) "Economics of a Biodiversity Convention." Ambio, 21 (3): 250-257. 


UNEP (1996) Sharing of Experiences on Incentive Measures for Conservation and Sustainable Use. 
Paper for the Third Meeting of the Conference of the Parties to the Convention on Biological Diversity,