Skip to main content

Full text of "Unemployment and American trade unions"

See other formats


JOHNS  HOPKINS  UNIVERSITY  STUDIES 

IN 

HISTORICAL  AND  POLITICAL  SCIENCE 

Under  the  Direction  of  the 

Departments  of  History,  Political  Economy,  and 
Political  Science 


VOLUME  XXXVII 


BALTIMORE 

THE  JOHNS  HOPKINS  PRESS 
1919 


COPYRIGHT  1919  BY 
THE  JOHNS  HOPKINS  PRESS 


PRESS  OF 

THE  HEW  ERA  PRINTING  COMPANY 
LANCASTER.  PA. 


CONTENTS 


PACK 
I.  UNEMPLOYMENT  AND  AMERICAN  TRADE  UNIONS.    By  D.  P. 

Smelser   I 

II.  THE  .LABOR  LAW  OF  MARYLAND.    By  Malcolm  H.  Lauch- 

heimer   155 

III.  THE  AMERICAN  COLONIZATION  SOCIETY,  1817-1840.     By  Early 

Lee  Fox 313 

IV.  THE  OBLIGATION   OF  CONTRACTS   CLAUSE  OF  THE  UNITED 

STATES  CONSTITUTION.    By  Warren  B.  Hunting 545 


UNEMPLOYMENT  AND  AMERICAN 
TRADE   UNIONS 


SERIES  xxxvn  No. 

JOHNS  HOPKINS  UNIVERSITY  STUDIES 

IN 

HISTORICAL  AND  POLITICAL  SCIENCE 

Under  the  Direction  of  the 

Departments  of  History,  Political  Economy,  and 
Political  Science 


UNEMPLOYMENT  AND  AMERICAN 
TRADE  UNIONS 


BY 

D.  P.  SMELSER,  PH.D. 
Captain,  Quartermaster  Corps,  A.  E.  F. 


BALTIMORE 

THE  JOHNS   HOPKINS  PRESS 
1919 


COPYRIGHT  1919  BY 
THE  JOHNS  HOPKINS  PRESS 


PRESS  OF 

THE  NEW  ERA  PRINTING  COMPANY 
LANCASTER.  PA. 


CONTENTS 

PACK 

PREFACE vii 

CHAPTER     I.     Statistics  of  Unemployment 9 

CHAPTER    II.     The  Trade  Union  Theory  of  Unemploy- 
ment     34 

CHAPTER  III.     Local  Union  Employment  Bureaus  ....  57 

CHAPTER  IV.     Union  Agencies  for  the  Distribution  of 

Workmen 75 

CHAPTER    V.     Distribution  of  Employment 109 

CHAPTER  VI.     Unemployment  Insurance   130 


PREFACE 

This  monograph  had  its  origin  in  an  investigation  carried 
on  by  the  author  while  a  member  of  the  Economic  Semi- 
nary of  the  Johns  Hopkins  University.  The  principal 
sources  of  information  have  been  the  trade-union  publica- 
tions contained  in  the  Johns  Hopkins  Library.  Document- 
ary evidence  was  also  supplemented  by  numerous  personal 
interviews  with  trade-union  officials. 

The  author  wishes  to  express  his  appreciation  of  the  help- 
ful criticism  and  advice  received  from  Professor  J.  H.  Hol- 
lander and  Professor  G.  E.  Barnett. 

D.  P.  S. 


UNEMPLOYMENT  AND  AMERICAN   TRADE 
UNIONS 


CHAPTER   I 
STATISTICS  OF  UNEMPLOYMENT 

Statistical  information  as  to  unemployment  in  the  United 
States  is  less  adequate  and  reliable  than  that  as  to  almost  any 
other  social  problem.  The  federal  government,  several  of 
the  States,  and  various  other  agencies  have  made  censuses 
of  the  unemployed  from  time  to  time,  but  in  the  greater 
number  of  cases  the  data  thus  secured  are  of  little  value. 

It  is  obvious  that  for  an  exhaustive  study  of  the  problem 
of  unemployment  there  must  exist  adequate  and  trustworthy 
statistical  information  upon  which  to  base  the  investigation. 
In  other  words,  the  problem  must  be  stated  before  it  can 
be  solved.  This  is  especially  true  for  a  study  of  the  methods 
which  the  trade  unions  use  in  meeting  the  problem,  since 
the  amount  and  character  of  the  unemployment  in  each  trade 
necessarily  determine  the  methods  which  each  trade  union 
uses.  Thus,  a  trade  union  a  majority  of  whose  members 
are  unemployed  during  certain  seasons  each  year  would 
not  be  likely  to  provide  for  the  payment  of  out-of-work 
benefits  during  these  periods,  but  would  attempt  to  estab- 
lish the  policy  of  equal  distribution  of  employment  and  en- 
courage their  members  to  seek  employment  in  other  occupa- 
tions. On  the  other  hand,  trades  in  which  the  state  of  em- 
ployment varies  considerably  from  one  community  to  another 
would  probably  attempt  to  establish  employment  bureaus  in 
order  to  transfer  their  members  from  one  city  to  another. 

It  will  be  the  aim  of  this  chapter  to  consider  the  sources 
of  statistical  information  as  to  unemployment  among  organ- 

9 


IO         UNEMPLOYMENT   AND   AMERICAN    TRADE   UNIONS 

ized  wage  earners,  to  consider  briefly  the  data  which  appear 
to  be  the  most  reliable,  and  to  attempt  to  determine  the  rela- 
tive volume  and  character  of  unemployment  in  some  of 
the  principal  trades,  in  order  to  show  how  different  the 
problem  is  in  the  various  trades  and  to  make  clear  that  con- 
ditions determine,  to  a  great  extent,  the  methods  which  each 
trade  union  employs  to  solve  it. 

The  sources  of  statistical  information  as  to  unemployment 
among  trade  unionists  are  the  publications  of  the  state  de- 
partments of  labor  and  of  the  trade  unions.  While  refer- 
ence will  be  made  to  all  the  data  which  have  been  collected, 
only  those  data  which  can  be  more  or  less  successfully  uti- 
lized in  the  study  will  be  particularly  described. 

The  New  York  Department  of  Labor  has  collected  since 
March,  1897,  statistics  of  unemployment  among  the  trade 
unionists  of  that  State.  From  1897  to  1914  it  collected  semi- 
annually,  from  all  the  trade  unions,  information  as  to  the 
number  of  members  employed  and  unemployed  on  the  last 
working  days  of  March  and  September,  the  causes  of  such 
unemployment,  the  number  of  members  idle  throughout  the 
first  and  third  quarters  of  the  year,  and  the  number  of  days 
which  each  member  worked  during  these  periods.  The 
supply  of  this  information  was  made  compulsory  by  law. 
Since  December,  1901,  the  New  York  Department  has 
selected  certain  local  unions  in  each  trade  and  industry  from 
which  it  has  secured  monthly  returns  as  to  unemployment. 
It  has  attempted  to  select  local  unions  which  have  reliable 
and  intelligent  secretaries,  to  have  each  trade  represented 
in  proportion  to  the  number  of  workmen  engaged  in  each 
class,  and  to  maintain  the  same  proportionate  representation 
from  month  to  month  so  that  the  data  may  be  comparable. 

Both  classes  of  statistics  are  of  doubtful  value.  The 
secretaries  of  the  local  unions  in  many  cases  had  no  means 
by  which  they  could  determine  the  actual  number  employed 
and  unemployed,  and  consequently  they  resorted  to  rough 
estimates.  Further,  there  was  a  tendency  to  exaggerate  the 
amount  of  unemployment  in  the  hope  that  this  would  favor- 


STATISTICS   OF   UNEMPLOYMENT 


II 


ably  affect  public  opinion.  These  defects  were  especially 
inherent  in  the  data  collected  semi-annually  from  all  unions, 
and  for  this  reason  the  collection  of  this  class  of  data  was 
discontinued  in  1914.  The  data  relating  to  selected  unions 
are  defective  in  many  respects,  but  it  is  thought  that,  while 
they  are  of  no  great  value  as  regards  the  actual  amount  of 
unemployment,  they  are  of  considerable  importance  in 
making  apparent  the  movements  in  the  state  of  employment 
from  month  to  month  and  from  year  to  year.  It  is  for  this 
reason  that  a  summary  of  the  data  thus  collected  is  given 
below.  It  may  be  well  to  state  that  these  statistics  represent 
about  235  local  unions  with  a  membership  of  150,000,  which 
is  about  25  per  cent  of  the  trade-union  membership  of  the 
State. 


STATE  OF  EMPLOYMENT  OF  ORGANIZED  LABOR  IN  NEW  YORK  STATE, 
AS  REPORTED  BY  REPRESENTATIVE  UNIONS,  1901  TO  1915 

(From  Bulletins  of  the  New  York  Department  of  Labor) 


Percentage  of  Members  Unemployed  on  Last  Working  Day  of 

Jan. 

Feb. 

Mar. 

Apr. 

May 

June 

July 

Aug. 

Sept. 

Oct. 

Nov. 

Dec. 

1902 

2O-9 

I8.7 

17-3 

15-3 

14.0 

H.5 

15-6 

7-i 

6.3 

II.  2 

14-3 

22.2 

1903 

29-5 

I7.8 

I7.6 

17-3 

2O.2 

23.1 

I7.8 

15-4 

9-4 

II.7 

16.4 

23-1 

1904 

25-8 

21.6 

27.1 

17.0 

15-9 

13-7 

14.8 

13-7 

I2.O 

10.8 

II.  I 

19.6 

1905 

22.5 

19.4 

19.2 

II.8 

8-3 

9-1 

8.0 

7.2 

5-9 

5.6 

6.1 

II.  I 

1906 

15.0 

15-3 

II.6 

7-3 

7.0 

6-3 

7-6 

5-8 

6-3 

6.9 

7-6 

15-4 

1907 

21-5 

20.1 

18.3 

IO.I 

10.5 

8.1 

8-5 

12.  1 

12.3 

18.5 

22.  0 

32.7 

1908 

36.9 

37-5 

37-5 

33-9 

32.2 

30.2 

26.8 

24.6 

24.6 

23.1 

21-5 

28.0 

1909 

29-3 

26.5 

23.0 

20.3 

17.1 

17.4 

13-9 

II.9 

14-5 

13-7 

13-3 

2O.6 

1910 

24.5 

22.4 

22.6 

16.0 

14-5 

15-4 

19.4 

22.3 

12.5 

15.0 

17-5 

27.3 

1911 

26.7 

24.8 

25.6 

21.3 

27.2 

22.9 

15-5 

11.7 

II.2 

II.6 

2O  .O 

34-2 

1912 

25-8 

17.6 

18.8 

13-3 

20.  1 

22.8 

21.  1 

9-1 

5-9 

7-4 

15-3 

30-1 

1913 

38.2 

33-4 

21.8 

21.7 

22.9 

22.2 

20.8 

i9.e 

16.2 

19-3 

27.8 

40.0 

1914 

32.3 

30-7 

28.3 

23-6 

22.7 

25-5 

32.5 

30.3 

24.3 

24-9 

35-8 

35-7 

1915 

40.1 

32.2 

27.4 

26.4 

31-8 

25.5 

26.0 

19-3 

14.9  12.7 

17.6 

21.9 

The  table  clearly  indicates  the  fluctuations  in  employment 
from  month  to  month  and  from  year  to  year.  During  1902, 
1903,  and  1904  the  average  percentage  of  unemployment  was 
around  13,  but  gradually  decreased  until  the  depression  of 
1907  and  1908  when  it  sharply  rose,  gradually  dropping  how- 
ever after  the  spring  of  1909.  During  1910  and  1911  the 


12         UNEMPLOYMENT  AND  AMERICAN   TRADE   UNIONS 

percentage  was  fairly  constant,  but  there  was  a  25  per  cent 
decrease  in  unemployment  in  1912 ;  for  several  of  the  months 
the  percentages  were  lower  than  they  had  been  for  five 
or  six  years.  However,  after  November,  1912,  the  percent- 
ages, if  we  disregard  seasonal  fluctuations,  gradually  rose 
until  the  fall  of  1915. 

It  will  be  noted  that  during  the  past  seven  years  an  aver- 
age of  between  20  and  25  per  cent  of  the  workmen  in  the 
selected  unions  have  been  returned  as  unemployed  on  the 
last  working  day  of  each  month.  The  minimum  percentage 
for  the  period  was  5.6  in  October,  1905,  while  the  maximum 
was  40.1  in  January,  1915.  The  instances  in  which  the 
monthly  percentage  was  under  10  number  less  than  twenty- 
five.  The  seasonal  fluctuations  are  clearly  indicated  in  the 
table.  January  reports  the  highest  percentage  of  the  year, 
after  which  the  percentage  drops  gradually  to  September 
and  October,  in  which  months  it  appears  that  there  is  less 
unemployment  than  at  any  other  time.  November  and  De- 
cember show  very  high  percentages. 

The  Massachusetts  Bureau  of  Statistics,  since  March, 
1908,  has  collected  data  as  to  unemplyoment  from  trade 
unions  situated  in  that  State.  This  information  is  compar- 
able, in  many  respects,  to  that  collected  by  the  New  York 
Department.  In  Massachusetts  information  as  to  unemploy- 
ment is  secured  only  from  those  unions  which  desire  to  re- 
port their  working  conditions.  However,  the  majority  of 
the  trade-union  membership  is  represented  in  the  returns. 
Thus,  for  the  quarter  ending  September  30,  1915,  returns 
were  made  by  1052  local  unions  representing  175,754  organ- 
ized wage  earners,  or  approximately  75  per  cent  of  the 
trade-union  membership  of  the  State.1  Monthly  returns  are 
not  made  by  any  of  the  unions,  reports  being  made  only 
for  the  last  working  days  of  the  four  quarters  of  the  year 
by  the  secretaries  of  the  local  unions.  The  returns  are 
scrutinized  by  the  bureau's  experts  and  if  any  errors  a~e 
apparent  the  schedules  are  returned  for  correction. 

1  The  Thirty-first  Quarterly  Report  on  Unemployment  in  Massa- 
chusetts :  Quarter  ending  September  30,  1915,  p.  I. 


STATISTICS   OF   UNEMPLOYMENT 


The  following  table  shows  the  percentage  of  members 
unemployed  at  the  end  of  each  quarter  from  March,  1908, 
to  December,  1915 : 

STATE  OF  EMPLOYMENT  OF  ORGANIZED  LABOR  IN  MASSACHUSETTS 
(From  Bulletins  of  the  Massachusetts  Bureau  of  Statistics) 


Percentage  of  Members  Unemployed. 

March  31 

June  30 

September  30 

December  31 

1908 

17.9 

144 

10.6 

13-9 

1909 

II.4 

6.4 

4.8 

94 

1910 

7-1 

7.0 

5-6 

10.2 

1911 

10.4 

6.6 

5.6 

9-7 

1912 

14.1 

5-3 

4-7 

9-1 

1913 

"•3 

6.4 

6.8 

10.4 

1914 

12.9 

9-9 

II.O 

18.3 

1915 

1  6.6 

10.6 

7-0 

8.6 

The  striking  fact  disclosed  by  these*  figures  is  their  great 
disparity  with  the  New  York  data.  When  idleness  due  to 
other  causes  than  lack  of  work,  lack  of  material,  and  the 
state  of  the  weather  has  been  eliminated,  the  averages  of 
the  New  York  and  Massachusetts  percentages  for  the  last 
working  days  of  the  four  quarters  of  the  year,  for  the 
period  1908-1915,  are  19.2  per  cent  and  7.5  per  cent  re- 
spectively. The  most  plausible  explanation  of  this  differ- 
ence is  the  larger  proportion  of  highly  seasonal  workmen 
represented  in  the  New  York  data.  In  the  reports  for  June 
30,  1915,  for  example,  the  building  trades  represent  more 
than  25  per  cent  of  the  workmen  included  in  the  New  York 
report,2  while  in  the  Massachusetts  figures  for  that  date 
the  returns  for  the  building  trades  constitute  less  than  20 
per  cent  of  the  total  figures.3  But  what  appear  to  be  of 
even  greater  importance  are  the  different  proportions  of 
the  totals  represented  by  garment  workers.  In  the  returns 
for  June,  1915,  the  garment  workers  constituted  21  per  cent 

2  Idleness  of  Organized  Wage  Earners  in  the  First-half  of  1915, 
Bulletin  of  the  New  York  Department  of  Labor,  whole  no.  73,  p.  n. 

8  Calculated  from  table  in  Thirteenth  Quarterly  Report  on  Unem- 
ployment in  Massachusetts,  June  30,  1915,  p.  n. 


14          UNEMPLOYMENT   AND   AMERICAN    TRADE   UNIONS 

of  those  included  in  the  New  York  returns,4  while  in  the 
Massachusetts  data  for  that  date  this  class  of  workmen 
formed  less  than  3  per  cent  of  the  members  reporting.5 
Unemployment  in  the  building  trades  and  in  the  garment 
industry  of  New  York  is  twice  as  great  as  the  average  in 
other  trades  taken  together.  Thus,  the  average  of  the 
monthly  percentages  of  unemployment  in  the  building  trades 
from  1907  to  1914  in  New  York  was  29,  and  that  for  the 
garment  industry  was  approximately  the  same,  while  the 
average  of  all  industries  was  only  22  per  cent.  When  it  is 
remembered  that  the  average  of  all  industries  is  weighted 
in  proportion  to  the  relative  representation  of  trades,  and 
that  the  garment  workers  and  building  trades  mechanics 
constitute  more  than  50  per  cent  of  the  total,  the  effect  of 
the  great  amount  of  unemployment  in  these  two  industries 
upon  the  average  percentage  is  easily  seen. 

The  New  Hampshire  Bureau  of  Labor  is  the  only  other 
state  bureau  which  has  collected  statistics  of  unemployment 
among  organized  wage  earners,  and  these  statistics  are  prac- 
tically valueless  as  they  give  only  the  percentages  of  mem- 
bers unemployed  throughout  the  first  and  second  quarters 
of  1915.  It  seems  that  the  secretaries  of  the  local  unions, 
in  most  cases,  were  unable  to  accurately  report-such  infor- 
mation. 

A  number  of  the  American  trade  unions  have  attempted 
to  collect  statistics  of  unemployment  of  their  members. 
Generally  these  attempts  have  failed,  either  because  the  sec- 
retaries of  the  local  unions  refused  to  report  conditions 
accurately,  or  because  the  secretary  of  the  national  union 
failed  to  recognize  the  importance  of  the  statistical  infor- 
mation as  to  unemployment.  The  unions  have  the  oppor- 
tunity of  collecting  such  material  at  small  expense.  In  all 
unions  the  secretaries  of  the  subordinate  branches  make 

monthly  reports  to  headquarters  concerning  various  sub- 

___— ^___ — __ ^^^— ^__— .^_____^^________— _^__^_-_—_ __^_____^___ . 

4  Bulletin  of  the  New  York  Department  of  Labor,  whole  no.  73, 
p.  ii. 

5  Calculated  from  table  in  Thirteenth  Quarterly  Report  on  Unem- 
ployment in  Massachusetts,  June  30,  1915,  p.  n. 


STATISTICS   OF   UNEMPLOYMENT  15 

jects,  and  where  statistical  information  as  to  unemployment 
has  been  collected  these  monthly  reports  have  generally  been 
utilized  for  this  purpose. 

The  American  Federation  of  Labor  collected  from  1899 
to  1908  data  relating  to  unemployment  among  members  of 
its  affiliated  unions.  The  number  of  workmen  represented 
in  the  returns  varied  as  much  as  800  per  cent  from  one 
month  to  another  in  the  same  year,  and  as  the  reports  were 
made  by  the  secretaries  of  the  national  unions  it  is  obvious 
that  the  data  secured  were  not  accurate.  For  this  reason 
the  collection  of  this  information  was  discontinued  in  1909. 

The  Wisconsin  State  Federation  of  Labor  has  collected 
statistics  of  unemployment  from  its  affiliated  unions  since 
1912.  The  information  collected  in  1912  was  worthless 
and  that  for  the  two  succeeding  years  was  far  from  satis- 
factory. In  1913  the  affiliated  unions  were  requested  to 
report  the  percentages  of  members  unemployed  on  Septem- 
ber i.  Returns  were  made  by  243  local  unions  with  a 
total  membership  of  19,921.  Of  these,  1436  members,  or 
7.2  per  cent,  were  reported  as  idle.6  This  percentage  is  but 
four-tenths  of  one  per  cent  higher  than  that  of  Massachu- 
setts for  September  30  of  the  same  year,  while  it  is  12.8 
lower  than  the  New  York  percentage  for  August  31. 

A  few  unions  have  realized  the  benefits  accruing  from  the 
collection  of  statistical  information  as  to  unemployment  and 
have  accordingly  provided  in  their  constitutions  that  the 
local  union  secretaries  shall  report  the  state  of  employment 
at  specified  periods.  For  example,  the  Potters,7  Plumbers,8 
Boilermakers,9  Iron  Holders,10  Lithographers,11  Elevator 
Constructors,12  and  Metal  Polishers13  require  the  secre- 

6  Labor  Conditions  in  Wisconsin :  Second  Report  by  the  Execu- 
tive Board  of  the  Wisconsin  State  Federation  of  Labor,  July  I, 
1914,  p.  15. 

7  Constitution,  1913,  sec.  132. 

8  Constitution,  1913,  sec.  36. 

9  Constitution  for  Local  Unions,  1914,  art.  2,  sec.  6. 

10  Constitution,  1912,  art.  5,  sec.  I. 

11  Constitution  for  Local  Unions,  1913,  art.  5,  sec.  I. 

12  Constitution,  1910,  art.  6,  sec.  3. 

13  Constitution,  1913,  art.  32,  sec.  I. 


16         UNEMPLOYMENT   AND   AMERICAN    TRADE    UNIONS 

taries  of  their  subordinate  unions  to  report  either  monthly 
or  quarterly  the  number  of  members  employed  and  unem- 
ployed. But  little  attention  is  paid  by  the  secretaries  to 
these  provisions,  and  in  the  unions  where  the  information 
is  reported  it  is  neither  used  by  the  general  secretaries  nor 
compiled  for  publication. 

The  Painters,  Paperhangers,  and  Decorators  at  their  con- 
vention in  1913 provided  that  an  official  "time  book"  should 
be  issued  to  each  member  of  the  union,  who  was  to  record 
in  it  all  time  lost  through  unemployment  and  the  causes  of 
such  idleness,  and  report  quarterly  to  his  local  union.  The 
secretaries  of  the  subordinate  branches  were  instructed  to 
compile  these  reports  and  send  them  to  the  national  union.14 
It  was  thought  that  much  valuable  information  could  thus 
be  secured.  Considerable  light  would  have  been  thrown 
upon  the  question  of  variation  in  unemployment  among 
localities.  However,  it  was  found  impossible 'to  secure  the 
desired  information  from  the  members  except  through  a 
system  of  fines,  which,  of  course,  would  have  had  a  tendency 
to  produce  inaccurate  statistics.  Consequently,  these  time 
books  are  used  in  only  a  few  unions.15  It  is  understood 
that  the  Chicago  local  union  has  collected  statistics  of  unem- 
ployment from  its  members  for  five  or  six  years.  It  was 
reported  at  the  convention  in  1913  that  the  data  collected 
in  the  two  previous  years  indicated  that  the  average  painter 
lost  ninety-eight  working  days  each  year  through  inability 
to  secure  work.16 

The  Glass  Bottle  Blowers  have  collected  and  privately 
published  statistical  information  as  to  unemployment  among 
its  members  for  several  years.  But  in  consequence  of  the 
fact  that  no  distinction  is  made  between  the  members  totally 
unemployed  and  those  working  as  "  spare  men  "  this  infor- 
mation is  of  little  value.  There  is  also  available  in  the 
monthly  journals  of  the  Wood  Carvers  data  as  to  the  num- 
ber of  members  employed  and  unemployed  on  the  last 

14  Constitution,  1913,  sec.  238. 

15  Interview  with  General  Secretary  Skemp,  August,  1915. 
18  Proceedings,  1913,  p.  635. 


STATISTICS   OF  UNEMPLOYMENT  17 

working  day  of  the  month.  Percentages  of  unemployment 
have  been  calculated  for  the  period  1909-1915,  and  there  is 
little  fluctuation  in  them  from  month  to  month  and  from 
year  to  year,  the  rate  of  unemployment  ranging  between 
twenty  and  twenty-five  per  cent.  This  would  seem  to  indi- 
cate that  the  returns  are  not  accurate  but  mere  estimates  of 
the  secretaries. 

The  only  statistics  of  unemployment  collected  by  the  trade 
unions  which  it  was  possible  to  utilize  in  this  study  are  the 
data  collected  by  the  Bricklayers,  Masons  and  Plasterers 
from  1882  to  1911,  by  the  Pattern  Makers  from  April,  1907, 
to  December,  1916,  and  by  the  Flint  Glass  Workers  from 
1907  to  1915. 

In  view  of  the  fact  that  so  little  attention  has  been  given 
to  the  collection  of  data  as  to  unemployment  in  the  United 
States  before  1900,  it  is  rather  surprising  to  find  that  the 
Bricklayers'  Union,  organized  in  1865,  collected  semi- 
annually  statistics  of  unemployment  from  1882  to  1911  and 
monthly  thereafter.17  These  statistics  are  based  upon  the 
reports  by  the  local  secretaries  of  the  number  of  members 
employed  and  unemployed.  Not  all  of  the  unions  reported, 
as  some  were  always  in  a  state  of  disorganization  or  were 
involved  in  labor  disputes ;  but  the  reports  are  fairly  repre- 
sentative of  the  entire  membership,  and  the  average  per- 
centage of  the  membership  included  in  the  data  for  the 
period  1882-1911  is  79.1.  There  is  no  reason  to  believe  that 
those  unions  which  are  not  represented  in  the  returns,  ex- 
cept the  few  on  strike,  had  more  or  less  unemployment  than 
the  average  of  those  reporting.  The  returns  unfortunately 
include  members  who  were  reported  as  unemployed  on  ac- 
count of  labor  disputes  and  illness.  Of  course  the  inclusion 
of  these  members  has  produced  high  percentages  of  unem- 
ployment. 

Another  important  question  is  whether  the  secretaries 
correctly  reported  the  number  of  the  unemployed.  Secre- 

17  The  data  collected  since  1911  have  not  been  compiled,  the  secre- 
tary merely  using  the  information.  (Interview  with  Secretary  Dob- 
son,  August,  1915.) 


18 


UNEMPLOYMENT   AND   AMERICAN    TRADE   UNIONS 


taries  of  unions  having  less  than  fifty  members  could  easily 
determine  the  number  of  unemployed,  since  they  generally 
knew  the  places  where  members  were  at  work ;  but  in  unions 
with  a  larger  membership — many  of  the  local  unions  have 
from  loo  to  7000  members — the  secretaries  were  unable  to 
make  exact  returns  from  their  own  knowledge.  In  such 
cases  the  secretaries  either  based  their  returns  upon  rough 
estimates  or  upon  the  reports  of  the  stewards.  It  is  impos- 
sible to  determine  the  extent  to  which  the  stewards'  reports 
were  used.  It  would  not  have  been  difficult  to  ascertain  the 
exact  number  of  members  employed  on  a  given  day  if  these 
reports  had  been  used,  because  each  week  the  stewards  on 
the  various  jobs  reported  the  names  of  all  members  work- 
ing on  particular  days.  The  reports  are  supposed  to  give 
the  number  of  members  employed  and  unemployed  on  the 
last  working  days  of  June  and  December;  but  it  is  under- 
stood that  frequently  the  returns  were  based  upon  the  con- 
dition of  trade  slightly  before  and  after  these  dates.  These 
data  are  presented  in  the  following  table,  principally  because 
they  represent  the  only  continuous  record  respecting  unem- 
ployment in  the  United  States  before  1897. 

UNEMPLOYMENT  OF   MEMBERS  OF  THE  BRICKLAYERS,   MASONS  AND 

PLASTERERS 

(From  Semi- Annual  Reports  of  the  General  Secretary) 


Year 

Percentage  of  Members 
Unemployed 

Year 

Percentage  of  Members 
Unemployed 

June                  December 

June 

December 

1882 

IO.O 

20.2 

1897 

41.4 

51-7 

I883 

4.6 

26.4 

1898 

38.8 

47-6 

1884 

1  1.  1 

48.6 

1899 

18.2 

31-2 

I885 

20.5 

33-6 

1900 

29.8 

34-7 

1886 

15-1 

36.7 

1901 

8.8 

20.9 

1887 

6.0 

37-1 

1902 

10.5 

23-8 

1888 

15-2 

37-3 

1903 

H-5 

45-8 

1889 

13-3 

34-1 

1904 

14.2 

36.9 

1890 

12.5 

37-1 

1905 

10.5 

23-4 

1891 

24.8 

37-2 

1906 

11.7 

24.0 

1892 

18.7 

37-6 

1907 

16.4 

51-2 

1893 

22.2 

67.7 

1908 

42.2 

48.8 

1894 

49-6 

54-6 

1909 

17.2 

30.1 

1895 

28.1 

43-2 

1910 

12.8 

30.2 

1896 

33.3 

55-9 

1911 

26.3 

STATISTICS   OF   UNEMPLOYMENT  19 

As  was  to  be  expected,  the  figures  show  great  differences 
in  unemployment  between  summer  and  winter.  Every  one 
realizes  that  there  is,  on  the  whole,  less  work  for  bricklay- 
ers in  December  than  in  June ;  but  few  realize  how  great 
the  difference  is.  December  31  and  June  30  may  be  taken 
as  dates  representative  of  the  poor  and  good  seasons  of 
employment  in  the  building  industry.  It  is  to  be  noted 
that,  without  exception,  in  the  period  1882-191 1  unemploy- 
ment was  greater  in  December  than  in  June  of  any  one 
year.  The  mean  of  the  December  figures  is  37.47  per  cent, 
while  the  mean  of  the  June  figures  is  only  19.84  per  cent. 
By  taking  the  average  of  the  percentages  for  the  two  sea- 
sons over  a  period  of  thirty  years  the  effects  of  special  cir- 
cumstances, cyclical  fluctuations,  and  general  changes  of 
level  may  be  eliminated  or  made  inappreciable,  and  the  sea- 
sonal fluctuation  alone  is  seen.  The  table  also  discloses  a 
remarkable  series  of  waves  of  good  and  bad  employment. 
The  average  unemployment  for  the  four  minima,  1882, 
1883,  1901,  1905,  is  15.6  per  cent  or  one-third  of  the 
maximum.  It  would  be  interesting,  if  the  statistics  of  a 
sufficient  number  of  years  were  available,  to  compare  this 
range  with  the  fluctuations  in  other  trades.  Beveridge  has 
shown  that  in  England  those  trades  which  are  most  regu- 
larly affected  by  seasonal  movement  from  month  to  month 
are  those  least  affected  by.  a  cyclical  fluctuation  from  year 
to  year.18  From  an  examination  of  the  existing  statistics 
in  the  United  States  it  appears  that  this  does  not  hold  true 
in  this  country. 

The  Flint  Glass  Workers  have  collected  quarterly  statis- 
tics of  unemployment  since  1907,  but  the  data  are  frag- 
mentary from  1907  to  1912.  In  1913  the  union  also  in- 
cluded in  its  inquiry  questions  as  to  the  number  of  members 
who  were  unemployed  at  the  trade,  but  who  had  secured 
temporary  employment  in  other  lines  of  industry.  Accord- 
ingly, the  local  unions  were  requested  to  report  the  number 
of  members  employed  at  the  trade,  the  number  holding  hon- 

18  W.  H.  Beveridge,  Unemployment :  A  Problem  of  Industry,  1909, 
p.  40. 


2O         UNEMPLOYMENT   AND   AMERICAN    TRADE   UNIONS 


orary  membership,  disabled,  and  working  outside  the  trade, 
and  the  number  of  those  who  were  willing  and  able  to  work 
but  had  not  found  employment  of  any  kind. 

The  following  table  shows  the  data  thus  collected : 

UNEMPLOYMENT  OF  MEMBERS  OF  THE  FLINT  GLASS  WORKERS  UNION 
(From  Quarterly  Reports  of  the  Secretary) 


Percentage  of  Members 

Employed 
at  Trade 

Employed 
Outside  Trade 

Unemployed 

1907  Aug.  31  

80 
82 
80 
87 
87 
84 
87 
85 
87 
87 
80 

90 

91 
90 
86 
87 
87 
84 

74 
76 
76 
81 
80 
85 

6 
8 

6 
8 
9 
13 
10 

7 
8 

9 

20 

18 
20 
13 
13 
16 

13 
15 
13 
13 

20 
IO 

9 
4 
6 
6 

8 

17 
II 

12 
12 
6 

Nov.  30  

1908  Feb.  28  

1909  Feb    28  

1910  Feb.  28  

May  31  

191  1  Feb.  28  

May  31      

1912  Feb    28  

May  31  

Aug.  31  

Nov.  30  

1913  Feb.  28  

May  31  

Aug.  31  

Nov.  30  

1914  Feb.  28  

May  31  

Nov.  30  

1915  Feb.  28  

May  31  

Aug.  31  

Nov.  30  

The  percentage  of  the  members  employed  at  the  trade, 
it  will  be  noted,  varied  from  74  on  August  31,  1914,  to  91 
on  February  28,  1913.  The  means  for  the  four  quarters 
for  the  period  1912-1915  were  83,  84,  78  and  81  per  cent. 
It  appears  that  the  state  of  employment  is,  on  the  average, 
practically  the  same  in  all  four  quarters.  Since  1913  of 
those  not  employed  at  the  trade  on  the  average  8.2  per  cent 
were  employed  outside  the  trade,  while  9.1  per  cent  were 
returned  as  unemployed. 

The  fact  that  many  workmen  secure  subsidiary  employ- 


STATISTICS   OF   UNEMPLOYMENT  21 

ment  when  they  are  unable  to  secure  employment  at  their 
principal  occupations  is  a  factor  that  has  frequently  been 
overlooked  in  discussions  of  unemployment  statistics.  The 
fact  that  the  unions  in  a  particular  trade  report  that  30  per 
cent  of  their  members  were  unemployed  on  a  certain  day 
should  not  be  construed  to  indicate  that  30  per  cent  of  their 
members  were  not  working,  but  that  30  per  cent  were  not 
engaged  at  their  principal  occupation.  This  defect  in  trade 
union  statistics  of  unemployment  is  due  to  the  fact  that  the 
secretary  of  a  local  union  estimates  the  percentages  of  un- 
employment with  the  idea  that  the  information  which  is 
most  desirable  is  that  relating  to  the  number  of  members 
who  are  unable  to  secure  employment  under  the  jurisdiction 
of  the  union. 

Statistical  information  as  to  unemployment  among  the 
members  of  the  Pattern  Makers'  Union  is  available  for  each 
month  since  April,  1907.  These  data  have  been  secured 
from  the  reports  of  the  local  union  secretaries  to  the  na- 
tional president  who  compiles  the  statistics  for  private  use 
and  for  publication.19  The  secretaries  are  instructed  to 
"give  the  exact  number  of  members  unemployed  at  the  end 
of  the  month"20  and  the  membership  of  the  local  unions. 
These  statistics  are,  of  course,  open  to  the  same  criticism 
as  those  of  the  New  York  Department  of  Labor  and  Massa- 
chusetts Bureau  of  Labor,  but  they  are  greatly  superior  to 
the  statistics  collected  by  trade  unions  that  have  heretofore 
been  considered.  In  January,  1915,  forty  of  the  sixty-five 
local  unions  of  the  Pattern  Makers  had  less  than  fifty  mem- 
bers each.21  As  was  stated  above,  the  secretaries  of  local 
unions  with  few  members  are  able  to  determine  the  number 
of  unemployed  from  personal  knowledge.  Moreover,  sev- 
eral of  the  larger  unions,  two  of  which  comprise  over  20 
per  cent  of  the  entire  membership,  pay  out-of-work  bene- 

19  The  writer  wishes  to  express  his  appreciation  of  the  kindness 
of  President  Wilson  of  the  Pattern  Makers  in  placing  at  his  dis- 
posal the  reports  from  which  these  data  have  been  obtained. 

20  Monthly  Financial  Statement  and  Trade  and  Statistical  Report, 
December,  1914,  p.  2. 

21  Ibid.,  January,  1915,  pp.  6,  7. 


22          UNEMPLOYMENT   AND   AMERICAN    TRADE   UNIONS 


fits,22  and  all  of  the  local  unions  furnish  out-of-work  stamps 
free  to  the  unemployed,23  so  that  their  secretaries,  unlike 
those  of  most  unions,  have  the  opportunity  of  ascertaining 
the  exact  number  of  unemployed  members  with  but  little 
difficulty.  The  president  of  the  union,  too,  takes  great  in- 
terest in  the  returns  and  where  a  local  union  attempts  to 
conceal  a  good  condition  of  trade  by  the  return  of  an  exag- 
gerated number  of  unemployed,  does  not  hesitate  to  correct 
the  error.  However,  President  Wilson  states  that,  although 
the  greater  number  of  unions  make  fairly  accurate  returns, 
some  associations  overestimate  the  number  of  unemployed 
for  the  purpose  of  deterring  the  traveling  members  from 
transferring  to  them.  Thus,  in  January,  1915,  he  pointed 
out  that  "one  association  this  month  reports  that  20  per 
cent  of  its  members  are  out  of  work  while  the  truth  is  that 
all  of  its  members  are  employed,  and  another  union  reports 
just  about  three  times  as  many  as  are  really  idle."24  As 
with  the  other  data  as  to  unemployment  in  trade  unions, 
these  figures  include  those  unemployed  from  all  causes.25 

The  following  table  shows  the  percentages  of  unemploy- 
ment in  the  Pattern  Makers'  Union  for  the  last  working  day 
of  each  month  from  April,  1907,  to  December,  1916: 

UNEMPLOYMENT  OF  MEMBERS  OF  THE  PATTERN  MAKERS'  UNION 
(From  Reports  at  the  Union  Headquarters) 


Year 

Percentage  of  Membership  Unemployed  on  Last  Working  Day 

J«. 

Feb. 

Mar. 

Apr. 

May  June 

July 

Aug. 

Sept. 

Oct. 

Nor. 

Dec. 

Mean 

1907 

3-8 

5-5!  4-9 

4-9 

6.8 

9-8 

12.5 

2O.6 

29-3 

IO.9 

I9C8 

28.6 

29.4 

28.1 

22.6 

27.1  26.4 

25.6 

23-7 

22.5 

21.7 

I7.I 

I6.7 

24.1 

1909 

15-3 

I4.I 

IO.2 

12.  1 

n.8  10.6 

8.2 

7-3 

6-5 

6.0 

6.2 

5-6 

9-5 

1910 

4.8 

3-9 

5-5 

4-3 

4-4    5-1 

5.5 

7.8 

8.1 

ii.  i 

10.6 

11.3 

6.8 

I9II 

10.5 

8.1 

7.6 

7.6 

9-3'  6.9 

7-2 

8.2 

8.1 

IO.I 

IO.I 

9.1 

8.6 

1912 

74 

6.3 

6-5 

5-2 

5-o;  4-9 

4-6 

4-5 

4-3 

3-8 

3-8 

4.8 

5-1 

1913 

4-6 

3-8 

3-9 

4-2 

6.2    7.4 

9-3 

11.4 

n.8 

12.9 

I5-I 

16.6 

8.9 

1914 

14.0 

12.5 

Il.q 

1  1.  3 

11.6  13.1 

12.8 

15-6 

20.3 

23-8 

23-9 

19.9 

15-9 

1915 

20.4 

16.5 

14.9 

I3-I 

ii.  8  10.9 

8-3 

7.8 

8-3 

7.0 

5-7 

5-7 

10.9 

1916 

5-8 

6.8 

6-3 

6.6 

6.5    5-6 

6.0 

6.6 

7-i 

5-9 

4-7 

3-9 

5-2 

'•  See  p.  144. 

23  See  p.  145. 

24  Monthly  Financial  Statement  and  Trade  and  Statistical  Report, 
January,  1915,  p.  2. 

25  In  1916  an  average  of  16.8  per  cent  of  the  members  reported  as 
unemployed  were  on  strike. 


STATISTICS   OF   UNEMPLOYMENT  23 

It  will  be  noted  that  the  percentages  are  considerably 
lower  than  those  of  the  other  unions  so  far  noted.  In 
normal  years  the  percentage  of  unemployment  is  between 
five  and  eight,  but  these  figures  are  doubled  in  periods  of 
industrial  depression.  The  striking  fact  about  the  data  of 
the  Pattern  Makers  is  the  relative  constancy  of  the  figures 
from  month  to  month ;  that  is  to  say,  the  percentages  show 
no  sudden  fluctuations  from  one  month  to  the  next  as  the 
unemployment  statistics  of  a  single  trade  generally  do,  but 
either  rise  or  fall  gradually  during  the  periods  of  depression 
and  prosperity.  Thus,  in  1915  the  percentage  was  20.4  in 
January  and  only  5.7  in  December,  but  the  percentages  for 
the  intervening  months  decreased  gradually.  The  same 
slow  movement  of  the  percentage  of  unemployment  oc- 
curred in  1907  when  there  was  a  gradual  increase  from  3.8 
in  April  to  29.3  in  December.  This  regularity  in  the  re- 
turns probably  indicates  that  the  secretaries  were  more  care- 
ful than  in  other  unions  to  note  slight  fluctuations. 

One  of  the  most  important  conclusions  to  be  drawn  from 
the  statistics  of  unemployment  relates  to  the  very  great 
differences  in  the  amount  of  unemployment  among  locali- 
ties. The  dominant  industries  of  any  two  States  are  rarely 
the  same,  or  even  if  the  same,  the  proportions  of  workmen 
employed  in  the  various  industries  are  generally  different. 
It  is  certainly  true,  for  example,  that  the  chief  occupations 
of  the  workmen  included  in  the  Massachusetts  returns  are 
not  identical  with  those  of  the  workmen  represented  in  the 
New  York  data.  Even  where  the  industries  are  the  same 
in  two  States  certain  local  peculiarities  may  affect  the  sea- 
sonal fluctuations  and  produce  more  unemployment  in  one 
state  than  in  another. 

The  differences  in  unemployment  among  various  States 
is  illustrated  by  a  comparison  of  the  monthly  fluctuations  in 
the  number  of  persons  employed  in  manufactures.  The 
census  of  manufacturers  of  1909  shows  that  in  ten  States  the 
minimum  number  of  wage  earners  reported  for  any  month 
in  the  year  represented  over  90  per  cent  of  the  maximum 


UNEMPLOYMENT   AND   AMERICAN   TRADE   UNIONS 


number.  In  thirteen  States  the  proportion  was  less  than 
80.0  per  cent.  The  largest  difference  between  the  maxi- 
mum and  the  minimum  numbers  employed  is  shown  for 
Idaho,  where  the  percentage  was  63.3.  This  was  due  chiefly 
to  the  seasonal  variations  in  the  lumber  industry  which  gave 
employment  to  more  people  than  any  other  industry.  In 
New  Hampshire  and  Vermont,  on  the  other  hand,  where 
the  fluctuations  in  the  various  industries  largely  balance  one 
another,  the  minimum  numbers  of  wage  earners  reported 
were  94.3  and  93.3  per  cent  respectively,  of  the  maximum 
numbers.26 

The  following  table  shows  the  relative  fluctuations  in  un- 
employment in  New  York  and  Massachusetts.  The  per- 
centage of  fluctuation  is  calculated  upon  the  base  of  the 
greatest  number  employed  in  any  one  month  of  the  year : 

MONTHLY  FLUCTUATIONS  OF  EMPLOYMENT  IN  THE  INDUSTRIES   OF 
NEW  YORK  AND  MASSACHUSETTS,  1909 

(From  the  Thirteenth  Census  of  the  United  States,  1910,  vol.  viii ; 
Manufactures,  p.  282) 


Jan. 

Feb. 

Mar. 

Apr. 

May 

June 

July 

Aug. 

Sept. 

Oct. 

Nov. 

Dec. 

Mean 

New  York 
Mass  

10.  1 

7.6 

8.7 
6.6 

6.8 
54 

6i 

5-8 

7-5 

5-9 

7.8 
6.0 

8.1 
6-5 

6.1 
5-2 

2.1 
2.9 

1.8 

0.4 
1.4 

1-7 

6.O2 
5-01 

The  table  shows  that  not  only  was  there  a  greater  fluctua- 
tion between  the  best  and  worst  months  of  employment  in 
New  York  than  in  Massachusetts,  but  that  in  New  York 
the  average  of  the  other  eleven  months  was  6.02  per  cent 
less  than  in  the  busiest  month,  October,  while  in  Massachu- 
setts the  average  was  only  5.01  per  cent  less  than  in  De- 
cember, the  busiest  month.  In  eight  of  the  eleven  months 
the  percentage  of  fluctuation  was  over  six  in  New  York, 
while  in  Massachusetts  the  percentage  was  six  or  over  in 
only  four  months. 

Not  only  are  the  fluctuations  in  employment  in  the  indus- 
tries of  two  States  taken  as  a  whole  often  quite  different, 

26  Thirteenth  Census,  1910,  vol.  viii,  p.  282. 


STATISTICS   OF   UNEMPLOYMENT  25 

but  it  frequently  happens  that  the  seasonal  fluctuations  in 
the  same  industry  are  different  in  two  States.  This  arises 
chiefly  out  of  climatic  conditions  although  various  local  pe- 
culiarities play  a  large  part.  Thus,  when  the  state  of  em- 
ployment in  the  building  trades  of  New  York  City  is  poor, 
Philadelphia  may  be  erecting  a  number  of  large  buildings 
and  may  need  additional  workmen.  Indeed  it  may  be  said 
that  the  state  of  employment  in  certain  trades  is  affected 
more  by  purely  local  variations  than  by  seasonal  and  cyclical 
fluctuations.  It  will  occasionally  happen  that  in  a  particu- 
lar city  more  building  will  be  done  during  the  winter  than 
was  done  in  the  preceding  summer.  Even  taking  the  labor 
market  as  a  whole,  the  state  of  employment  varies  as  much 
from  one  city  to  another  as  it  does  from  one  season  to  an- 
other. This  fact  is  shown  by  the  reports  of  the  Massachu- 
setts Bureau  of  Statistics  on  the  state  of  .employment  in  the 
various  cities  of  the  State.  In  March,  1915,  for  example, 
the  percentage  of  unemployment  for  the  entire  State  was 
16.6;  in  Boston,  it  was  13.9,  in  Brockton,  27.6,  in  Holyoke, 
25.2,  in  Lowell,  7.4,  while  in  Quincy  and  Taunton  it  was 
only  4.1  and  4.7,  respectively.21  Thus,  there  was  a  total 
range  of  23.5  from  one  city  to  another  in  the  same  State. 
The  reports  of  the  New  York  Department  of  Labor  show 
that  the  state  of  employment  is  generally  far  worse  in  New 
York  City  than  in  other  parts  of  the  State. 

The  difference  in  the  amount  of  unemployment  among 
cities  is  illustrated  by  the  statistics  of  "traveling"  among 
trade  unionists.  Workmen  do  not  move  from  one  city  to 
another  because  the  general  state  of  employment  in  their 
trade  is  poor,  but  because  it  is  poor  in  the  particular  com- 
munity in  which  they  reside.  It  is  true  that  some  twenty 
years  ago  trade  unionists  traveled  needlessly  from  one  local 
union  to  another,  but  in  consequence  of  the  change  in  the 
attitude  of  the  unions,  the  members  are  notified  of  the  con- 
dition of  trade  in  contiguous  cities  before  they  move,  and 
if  it  appears  to  the  secretary  or  business  agent  that  the 

27  Twenty-ninth  Quarterly  Report  on  Unemployment  in  Massa- 
chusetts, March  31,  1915,  p.  4. 


26 


UNEMPLOYMENT   AND   AMERICAN    TRADE    UNIONS 


UNEMPLOYMENT  AND  TRAVELING  IN  THE  PATTERN  MAKERS'  UNION 


Year 


Month 


Percentage 
Unemployed 


1909  January 15.3 

February 14. 1 

March 10.2 

April 12.1 

May n.8 

June 10.6 

July 8.2 

August 7.3 

September 6.5 

October 6.0 

November 6.2 

December 5.6 

1910  January 4.8 

February 3.9 

March 5.5 

April 4.3 

May 4.4 

June 5.1 

July 5-5 

August 7.8 

September 8.1 

October ll.l 

November 10.6 

December 11.3 

191 1  January 10.5 

February 8.1 

March 7.6 

April 7.6 

May 9.3 

June 6.9 

July 7-2 

August 8.2 

September 8.1 

October 10.1 

November 10.1 

December 9.  i 

1912  January 7.4 

February 6.3 

March 6.5 

April 5.2 

May 5.0 

June 4.9 

July 4.6 

August 4.5 

September . 4.3 

October 3.8 

November 3.8 

December 4.8 

1913  January .  4.6 

February 3.8 


STATISTICS   OF   UNEMPLOYMENT 


UNEMPLOYMENT  AND  TRAVELING  IN  THE  PATTERN  MAKERS'  UNION 
(Continued) 


Year 


Month 


Percentage 
Unemployed 


Number 
of  Members 

per  1,000 
Transferred 


1913  March 3.9 

April 4.2 

May 6.2 

June 74 

July 9-3 

August 11.4 

September II.o 

October 12.9 

November 15.1 

December 16.6 

1914  January 14.0 

February 12.5 

March 1 1 .9 

April 11.3 

May 11.6 

June "13.1 

July 12.8 

August 15.6 

September 20.3 

October 23.8 

November 23.9 

December 19.9 

1915  January 20.4 

February 16.5 

March 14.9 

April 13.1 

May n.8 

June 10.9 

July 8.3 

August 7.8 

September 8.3 

October 7.0 

November 5.7 

December 5.7 


18 
23 
25 

21 
23 

18 
19 
H 
13 

12 
II 
IO 
17 
13 
IO 
16 

12 

13 
10 

8 

9 

8 

10 

10 
12 
13 
17 
13 
21 

17 

16 

20 

18 


member  would  not  be  bettering  his  chances  of  employment 
by  transferring  his  residence,  the  workman  is  informed  of 
the  fact.  The  trade  unionists,  as  will  be  shown  in  a  later 
chapter,  are  relying  more  and  more  upon  their  unions  to 
notify  them  of  employment  in  other  cities  and  consequently 
the  movement  that  occurs  at  the  present  time  is  largely  due 
to  differences  in  the  demand  for  labor  in  various  cities.  It 
has  frequently  been  asserted  in  periods  of  depression  that 


28          UNEMPLOYMENT   AND   AMERICAN    TRADE   UNIONS 

the  poor  condition  of  trade  forced  many  workmen  to  move 
from  one  city  to  another,  but  the  contrary  is  true.  This  is 
clearly  brought  out  by  comparing  the  percentage  of  unem- 
ployment and  the  number  of  transfers  issued  per  one  thou- 
sand members  in  the  Pattern  Makers'  Union,  as  shown  in 
the  table  on  pages  26  and  27. 

The  coefficient  of  correlation  between  the  number  unem- 
ployed and  the  number  transferred  is  — .70.  In  other  words, 
the  percentage  of  unemployment  varies  inversely  with  the 
percentage  of  transfers  issued.  As  unemployment  in- 
creases, the  number  of  workmen  transferring  from  one  city 
to  another  decreases,  and  vice  versa.  The  percentage  of 
transfers  is  governed  by  the  fluctuations  of  employment  be- 
tween individual  labor  markets. 

From  the  statistics  of  unemployment  we  are  also  able  to 
make  certain  deductions  as  to  the  relative  volume  and  char- 
acter of  unemployment  in  some  of  the  principal  trades. 
Cyclical  fluctuations  occur  with  some  degree  of  regularity, 
the  movement  covering  a  period  of  four  or  five  years. 
Thus,  1896,  1900,  1904,  and  1908  were  years  in  which  the 
percentage  of  unemployment  reached  very  high  marks. 
These  cyclical  fluctuations  affect  all  trades  and  industries. 
It  appears  that  a  depression  generally  causes  an  increase  at 
the  high  point  of  50  per  cent  over  the  number  normally 
idle.  Thus,  in  Massachusetts  it  appears  that  there  was,  on 
the  average,  61  per  cent  more  unemployment  in  1908  and 
1904  than  in  the  intervening  years  while  in  New  York 
there  was,  on  the  average,  50  per  cent  more  unemployment 
in  1908  and  1914  than  the  average  of  the  intervening  years. 
The  number  unemployed  does  not  register  the  full  effect 
of  a  depression  since  short-time  is  more  common  in  such 
periods.  The  amount  of  the  weekly  pay-roll  would  be  a 
better  measure,  but  the  data  are  not  obtainable.  Industrial 
depressions  affect  the  various  trades  in  different  degree. 
For  instance,  a  period  of  depression  causes  an  increase  of 
loo  per  cent  in  the  number  of  unemployed  in  the  building 
trades,  while  it  causes  increases  of  only  30  per  cent  in  the 


STATISTICS   OF   UNEMPLOYMENT  29 

garment  industry,  40  per  cent  in  food  and  liquors,  and  prac- 
tically none  in  some  other  trades  and  in  public  employment. 

There  are  two  methods  by  which  the  trade  unions  can 
alleviate  the  consequences  of  unemployment  due  to  cyclical 
fluctuations:  (i)  distribution  of  employment  and  (2)  un- 
employment insurance.  It  is  obvious  that  the  unions  can 
of  themselves  do  nothing  to  regularize  industry.  In  pe- 
riods of  depression,  their  employment  bureaus  cannot  have 
any  great  value,  nor  can  they  place  their  members  in  other 
occupations,  because  industries  are  generally  affected.  Equal 
distribution  of  employment  and  unemployment  insurance 
appear  to  be  the  only  means  of  meeting  cyclical  fluctuations. 
But,  as  will  be  pointed  out  in  a  later  chapter,  various  forces 
operate  against  the  establishment  of  the  system  of  equal 
distribution  of  employment.  Thus,  in  transportation  and 
printing  where  a  period  of  depression  throws  out  of  em- 
ployment only  about  four  per  cent  of  the  workmen,  this 
number  is  not  large  enough  to  cause  the  unions  to  ask  for 
an  equal  distribution  of  the  work.  The  system  is  most  used 
in  those  trades  where  the  cyclical  and  seasonal  fluctuations 
are  the  most  violent.  In  the  building  trades,  however, 
where  the  workmen  change  frequently  from  one  employer 
to  another,  this  method  can  be  utilized  only  with  great 
difficulty. 

The  most  noticeable  characteristic  of  the  statistics  is  the 
wide  fluctuation  in  the  percentages  of  unemployment  from 
month  to  month.  In  the  New  York  data,  which  constitutes 
the  only  statistical  information  as  to  unemployment  from 
month  to  month  in  all  trades,  the  percentages  for  all  trades 
taken  together  gradually  dropped  from  January,  the  dullest 
month  in  the  year,  to  September  and  October,  and  rose 
again  in  November  and  December.  The  good  and  bad  sea- 
sons vary  from  one  trade  to  another.  Thus,  the  winter 
months  furnish  less  employment  in  building  trades  and 
transportation,  but  more  employment,  in  clothing,  textiles, 
boots  and  shoes,  theatres  and  music.  The  differences  among 
the  various  trades  of  the  same  industry  are  equally  as  im- 


3O         UNEMPLOYMENT   AND   AMERICAN    TRADE   UNIONS 

portant.  For  instance,  in  the  garment  industry,  the  dull 
seasons  in  dresses  and  waists  coincide  with  the  periods  of 
fairly  intense  activity  in  the  manufacture  of  petticoats. 
While  the  seasons  of  activity  and  dullness  may  be  in  gen- 
eral the  same  in  some  of  the  various  industries,  the  duration 
and  the  intensity  of  the  unemployment  may  be  different.  In 
the  clothing  industry  the  seasonal  fluctuations  are  the  great- 
est, for  in  some  of  its  trades  there  is  an  almost  complete 
stagnation  in  the  dull  season.  On  the  average,  it  may  be 
said  that  the  dull  season  affects  80  per  cent  of  the  workmen 
in  the  clothing  industry.  In  the  building  trades  the  fluc- 
tuations due  to  weather  conditions  mean  the  idleness  of  20 
per  cent  of  the  workmen  in  addition  to  the  number  normally 
idle.  In  metals  and  machinery  and  printing,  the  seasonal 
fluctuations  are  less,  amounting  to  but  three  or  four  per 
cent  of  the  workmen.  In  the  brewing  industry  the  seasonal 
fluctuations  mean  the  employment  of  all  workers  on  half 
time,  while  in  theatres  about  75  per  cent  of  the  workmen 
are  unemployed  during  the  summer  months. 

There  are  two  chief  remedies  recommended  for  seasonal 
fluctuations:  (i)  the  regularization  of  industry  and  (2)  the 
dovetailing  of  occupations.  While  it  is  true  that  the  trade 
unions  could  facilitate  the  regularization  of  industry  by 
lowering  their  minimum  rates  in  the  dull  seasons,  there  are 
certain  considerations  which  make  this  solution  undesirable 
to  them.  Moreover,  this  solution  can  only  be  achieved  by 
cooperation  with  the  employers. 

The  second  remedy,  the  dovetailing  of  trades,  has  greater 
possibilities,  although  the  trade  unions  have  given  it  little 
attention.  In  a  later  chapter,  it  will  be  pointed  out  that 
only  a  few  of  the  unions  have  provided  for  a  free  inter- 
change of  union  cards.  It  was  noted,  however,  in  our  ex- 
amination of  the  statistics  of  the  Flint  Glass  Workers  union, 
that  nearly  one-half  of  those  not  engaged  at  their  principal 
occupations  were  employed  at  other  work.  In  this  prob- 
lem, as  in  others,  the  volume  and  character  of  the  unem- 
ployment determine  to  a  great  extent  the  appropriate  rem- 


STATISTICS   OF   UNEMPLOYMENT  3! 

edy.  It  is  obvious  that  the  amount  of  dovetailing  will  be 
greatest  in  those  trades  where  the  slack  seasons  are  most 
pronounced.  The  flint  glass  workers,  the  theatrical  stage 
employees,  and  the  glass  bottle  blowers,  who  realize  that 
they  will  be  unable  to  secure  any  employment  at  their  main 
occupation  during  the  dull  seasons,  look  to  other  industries 
for  employment  to  tide  them  over  the  slack  period.  On 
the  other  hand,  where  the  fluctuations  are  less  pronounced, 
and  there  is  a  greater  chance  for  continued  employment  in 
the  trade  through  the  slack  season,  the  workmen  are  reluc- 
tant to  enter  other  industries  and  perform  work  which  is 
more  irksome  for  lower  wages.  This  explains  in  great 
part  why  the  longshoremen  rarely  enter  other  fields  of  em- 
ployment even  for  short  periods ;  there  is  always  the  chance 
that  they  can  secure  some  work  along  the  wharves. 

In  another  group  of  trades,  workmen  are  unable  to  dove- 
tail occupations  because  there  are  no  opportunities.  The 
coal  miners  have  no  means  of  supplementing  their  earnings 
in  dull  seasons,  and  charity  workers  will  testify  to  the  fact 
that  clothing  workers  are  usually  unable  to  secure  work  at 
other  than  the  needle  trades.  Skilled  workmen  are  re- 
luctant to  do  unskilled  work  for  fear  that  they  will  in  some 
way  destroy  the  knack  of  doing  skilled  work ;  it  is  only  in 
a  small  number  of  cases  that  building  trades  workers  secure 
employment  in  other  occupations  with  somewhat  lower 
wages.  Thus,  the  extent  to  which  resort  is  had  to  sub- 
sidiary occupations  varies  from  trade  to  trade.  In  trades 
where  the  seasonal  fluctuations  are  more  pronounced,  a  con- 
siderable part  of  the  number  not  employed  at  the  trade  are 
employed  in  some  other  occupation.  In  the  highly  skilled 
trades  and  in  trades  where  the  fluctuations  are  not  very 
acute,  the  number  is  very  much  less. 

The  consequence  of  seasonal  unemployment  to  the  indi- 
vidual workmen  may  be  alleviated  by  unemployment  insur- 
ance, by  relatively  higher  wages  during  employment,  and  by 
distribution  of  employment. 

It  has  been  noted  that  the  periods  of  seasonal  fluctuations 


32         UNEMPLOYMENT  AND  AMERICAN   TRADE   UNIONS 

in  many  trades  are  well  defined,  and  the  workmen  expect  to 
be  unemployed  for  a  certain  length  of  time  each  season. 
Unemployment  insurance,  in  such  cases,  is  not  necessary 
unless  the  workmen  have  not  the  will  to  provide  for  these 
periods  of  idleness.  It  will  be  noted  later  that  the  Cigar 
Makers  do  not  provide  for  the  payment  of  out-of-work 
benefits  during  the  seasonal  periods  of  slackness. 

It  is  a  well  recognized  fact  that  wages  are  higher  in 
trades  which  are  affected  by  pronounced  seasonal  fluctua- 
tions than  in  trades  embracing  the  same  class  of  workmen 
but  with  greater  regularity  of  employment.  Thus,  the 
hourly  wages  of  bricklayers  are  considerably  higher  than  the 
wages  of  carpenters;  but  the  statistics  of  the  New  York 
Department  of  Labor  show  that  the  average  yearly  earnings 
in  the  two  trades  are  about  the  same.  Cabinet  makers  re- 
ceive lower  wages  than  carpenters  partly,  if  not  entirely, 
becaus.e  they  have  more  regular  employment.  The  rela- 
tively high  daily  wages  of  members  of  building-trades 
unions  are  frequently  used  to  indicate  high  yearly  earnings, 
yet  it  is  found  that  the  latter  are  but  little  more  than  those 
in  metals  and  machinery  and  slightly  lower  than  in  printing, 
where  regular  employment  produces  high  yearly  earnings 
although  the  daily  wage  is  relatively  low. 

In  a  later  chapter  it  will  be  shown  that  the  unions  depend 
chiefly  upon  the  distribution  of  employment  in  meeting 
seasonal  fluctuations,  and  that  the  volume  and  character  of 
the  unemployment  play  a  considerable  part  in  determining 
whether  or  not  this  method  is  available. 

Apart  from  seasonal  and  cyclical  unemployment  there  is 
a  considerable  amount  of  unemployment  in  certain  trades 
which  is  due  to  the  maladjustment  of  the  labor  supply 
among  different  localities.  Against  this  form  of  unemploy- 
ment, the  unions  have  provided  by  the  transfer  of  their 
members  from  one  city  to  another.  These  methods  are 
generally  better  established  in  trades  where  the  local  fluctua- 
tions are  the  greatest. 

Finally,  there   is   the   form  of  unemployment  which  is 


STATISTICS   OF   UNEMPLOYMENT  33 

present  at  all  times,  caused  either  by  a  chronic  oversupply  of 
workmen  in  the  trade  or  by  the  fact  that  workmen  are 
sometimes  forced  to  change  their  employers.  The  former 
cause  is  of  importance  only  in  those  trades  where  the  work 
is  extremely  casual  as  in  the  case  of  longshoremen.  In  this 
connection  the  unions  have  done  little;  indeed  Barnes28 
points  out  that  the  unions  of  longshoremen  in  New  York 
City  have  repeatedly  refused  the  offers  of  the  employers 
to  place  a  certain  number  of  the  men  on  weekly  wages. 

The  second  form  of  unemployment,  that  due  to  the  chang- 
ing of  employers,  is  of  great  importance  in  some  trades, 
while  in  others  it  is  not  a  serious  problem.  More  time  is 
lost  in  this  manner  in  the  building  trades  than  in  any  other 
industry.  The  average  building-trades  worker  secures  em- 
ployment on  several  jobs  and  under  several  employers  dur- 
ing a  season.  Inasmuch  as  the  periods  of  unemployment 
in  such  cases  are  generally  short,  unemployment  insurance 
is  of  little  value.  The  most  important  need  is  for  employ- 
ment bureaus.  In  a  later  chapter  it  will  be  noted  that  the 
unions  have  developed  these  agencies  in  proportion  to  the 
relative  volume  of  such  unemployment  in  their  trades. 
Thus,  in  the  building  trades  where  the  problem  is  the 
greatest,  the  office  of  business  agent  has  been  established. 
In  other  trades,  as,  for  instance,  the  glass  industry,  where 
the  problem  is  far  less  acute,  the  unions  have  done  very 
little. 

28  Charles  B.  Barnes,  The  Longshoremen,  pp.  74,  79,  102. 


CHAPTER   II 
THE  TRADE  UNION  THEORY  OF  UNEMPLOYMENT 

The  American  unions  have  adopted  certain  policies  which 
have  as  their  object  a  solution  of  the  problem  of  unem- 
ployment. Some  of  these  policies  are  based  on  fallacious 
reasoning,  while  others  would  produce  a  partial  solution  if 
the  unions  were  able  to  exercise  jurisdiction  over  a  greater 
proportion  of  the  working  population  than  they  now  control. 
No  one  realizes  the  inadequacy  of  present  policies  better 
than  the  trade  unionists,  and  they  also  realize  that  without 
the  aid  of  the  government,  of  the  employers,  and  of  the 
general  public,  they  cannot  deal  successfully  with  the  prob- 
lem. As  one  trade-union  official  has  said:  "Of  all  the 
problems  facing  trade-union  officials  that  of  unemployment 
is  the  most  difficult  to  handle."1 

There  are  numerous  union  rules,  regulations,  customs,  and 
policies  which  bear  some  relation  to  unemployment,  but  only 
those  which  show  the  union  theory  of  unemployment  will  be 
considered  here.  Inasmuch  as  this  theory  has  been  de- 
veloped from  two  main  ideas,  the  regulation  of  the  number 
of  workmen  among  whom  the  employment  is  to  be  divided, 
and  the  increasing  of  the  total  amount  of  employment,  the 
policies  which  have  been  chosen  for  discussion  may  be  con- 
veniently classified  under  these  two  heads. 

Unions  generally  regard  the  amount  of  work  which  is  to 
be  done  as  a  fixed  quantity.  Their  chief  concern,  there- 
fore, is  the  number  of  workmen  among  whom  the  employ- 
ment is  to  be  divided.  The  problem  of  unemployment 
would  be,  in  great  measure,  solved,  in  their  opinion,  could 
they  but  regulate  the  number  of  workmen  in  the  country 
and  in  each  trade.  Thus,  the  unions  have  been  the  strongest 

1  Typographical  Journal,  January,  1915,  p.  42. 

34 


TRADE    UNION   THEORY   OF   UNEMPLOYMENT  35 

agitators  for  a  restriction  of  immigration.  They  maintain 
that  as  the  population  of  the  country  increases  the  chances 
for  employment  lessen  and  there  is  less  amount  of  employ- 
ment per  capita.  In  the  same  manner  they  appear  to  think 
that  by  the  abolition  of  the  manufacture  of  goods  by  con- 
vict and  child  labor  the  per  capita  amount  of  work  will  be 
increased.  In  short,  the  union  theory  of  unemployment  is 
built  upon  the  doctrine  which  economists  have  termed  the 
"work  fund"  theory. 

In  view  of  the  existence  of  such  union  theories,  it  is  not 
surprising  that  a  great  number  of  unions  have  placed  re- 
strictions upon  the  admission  of  workmen  to  their  organiza- 
tions. The  editor  of  the  Bridge  and  Structural  Iron  Work- 
ers Journal  has  stated  the  common  union  view  as  follows : 
"  As  a  general  proposition  with  us  we  appear  to  think  that  a 
new  applicant  means  another  person  to  apply  for  the  various 
jobs."2 

Not  all  of  the  unions  have  adopted  the  policy  of  limiting 
their  membership;  many  are  willing  to  receive  as  members 
practically  all  who  are  employed  at  the  trade.  But,  where 
a  local  union  has  the  field  sufficiently  organized  to  success- 
fully deal  with  the  employers,  very  little  effort  is  made  to 
secure  additional  members.  In  some  of  the  large  cities 
it  is  very  difficult  to  obtain  admission  to  a  building-trades 
union.  In  such  cases  it  is  felt  that  workmen  have  the  local 
situation  so  well  in  hand  that  the  presence  of  even  a  con- 
siderable number  of  unorganized  workmen  can  have  little 
influence  in  their  dealings  with  the  employers. 

A  few  local  unions  in  various  trades  make  their  admission 
fees  high  as  a  barrier  to  deter  the  unorganized  from  joining. 
Initiation  fees  of  $50.00,  $75.00  and  even  $100.00  are  found 
in  a  few  highly  organized  unions,  and  this  amount  must  be 
paid  before  the  workmen  are  given  their  working  cards. 
Another  method  of  keeping  the  unorganized  out  of  the 
union  is  to  make  the  conditions  of  the  examination  such 
that  it  is  very  difficult  for  ordinary  workmen  to  pass  it. 

2  Bridgemen's  Magazine,  1908,  p.  848. 


36         UNEMPLOYMENT   AND   AMERICAN   TRADE   UNIONS 

The  New  York  local  union  of  Steam  Fitters  limits  its  mem- 
bership by  this  method.  The  requirements  of  the  examina- 
tion are  said  to  be  of  such  a  nature  that  a  majority  of  the 
members  of  the  union  could  not  pass  it.  Other  unions  have 
gone  further  and  have  absolutely  refused  to  consider  ap- 
plications. While  this  is  a  policy  of  only  two  or  three 
national  unions,  it  is  practised  in  a  great  number  of  local 
unions  of  various  trades.  These  local  unions  have  a  suffi- 
cient number  of  members  to  maintain  relations  with  the  em- 
ployers and  are  extremely  reluctant  to  receive  any  new  mem- 
bers, even  upon  application.  A  still  greater  number  of 
local  unions  do  not  make  any  serious  efforts  to  organize  their 
trade.  Thus,  a  business  agent  informed  the  writer  that 
he  made  no  effort  to  secure  new  members  and,  further,  that 
he  attempted  to  persuade  applicants  not  to  join  the  union 
unless  work  was  very  plentiful.3 

The  union  apprenticeship  policies  are  dominated  by  the 
same  ideas.  The  unions  seek  to  perpetuate  the  custom  of 
apprenticeship  with  its  accompanying  rules,  primarily,  in 
order  that  the  supply  of  labor  may  be  regulated  and,  sec- 
ondarily, that  capable  workmen  may  be  produced.  Although 
there  is  no  desire  to  minimize  the  purpose  of  the  unions  to 
produce  efficient  workmen  by  the  system  of  apprenticeship, 
it  is  obvious  that  this  is  subordinate  to  the  desire  to  restrict 
the  number  working  at  the  trade.  In  those  trades  in  which 
the  system  of  apprenticeship  exists,  a  considerable  amount 
of  unemployment  is  frequently  traced  by  the  unions  to  the 
admission  of  too  many  apprentices.  Thus,  an  official  of  the 
Photo-Engravers  reported  in  1915:  "We  fully  agree  that 
one  of  the  chief  contributing  factors  that  have  been  the 
cause  of  so  much  unemployment  in  our  trade  has  been  a  too 
liberal  apprentice  ratio  which  is  turning  out  more  journey- 
men than  the  trade  can  absorb.  The  industry  is  not  growing 
as  rapidly  as  it  has  in  the  past  and  the  new  time  and  labor 
saving  methods  and  processes  are  aggravating  this  situation. 
.  .  .  We  therefore  .  .  .  urge  this  convention  to  alter  our 

8  Interview,  February,  1913. 


TRADE   UNION    THEORY   OF   UNEMPLOYMENT  37 

existing  ratio  of  apprentices  so  as  to  be  more  restrictive."* 
Trade  unionists  generally  believe  that  if  the  unions  were 
allowed  to  fix  the  ratio  of  apprentices  to  journeymen,  the 
problem  of  unemployment  would  be  greatly  lessened.  Thus, 
the  president  of  the  Plumbers  said  in  1900:  "I  believe  that 
the  future  prosperity  of  our  trade  lies  in  restricting  the  vast 
number  of  apprentices  that  are  at  present  employed.  The 
supply  is  greater  than  the  demand  and  therefore  in  accord- 
ance with  the  other  lines  of  trade  we  should  endeavor  to 
restrict  the  number  of  apprentices  until  such  time  as  our 
older  members  have  an  opportunity  to  earn  a  livelihood."5 
In  the  majority  of  trade  conferences,  such  as  those  in  the 
glass  industry,  the  subject  of  apprenticeship  is  one  of  the 
most  important  topics  of  discussion.  The  unions  demand 
that  the  ratio  be  reduced  while  the  employers  desire  an  in- 
crease. Frequently  the  unions  have  laid  as  much  stress 
upon  this  point  as  upon  wages  and  other  working  conditions. 
The  relation  between  restriction  of  numbers  and  the 
avoidance  of  unemployment  is  illustrated  by  the  policies  of 
certain  unions  when  trade  is  very  active.  In  such  cases  the 
unions  occasionally  remove  the  barriers  to  membership  in 
order  to  furnish  employers  with  the  desired  number  of 
workmen.  They  receive  these  men  into  the  union  upon  the 
payment  of  the  customary  initiation  fee,  but  are  careful  to 
accept  as  members  only  enough  to  meet  the  demands  of 
the  employers.  In  other  cases  the  unions  do  not  accept  as 
regular  members  those  workmen  who  are  needed  by  reason 
of  an  increased  demand.  For  instance,  the  Elevator  Con- 
structors, which  has  limited  its  membership  more  success- 
fully than  any  other  American  union,  utilizes  the  so-called 
"  permit "  system.  A  Chicago  contractor  stated  in  1904  that 
"in  busy  times  the  Union  (Elevator  Constructors)  will  not 
admit  new  members  so  that  all  of  its  members,  even  the 
poorest,  may  be  able  to  obtain  employment,"  and  that  this 
resulted  in  a  shortage  of  efficient  men.6 

*  American  Photo-Engraver,  October,  1915,  pp.  467-468. 
5  Proceedings,  1900,  p.  15. 

8  Eleventh  Special  Report  of  the  Commissioner  of  Labor,   1904, 
P-  333- 


38          UNEMPLOYMENT   AND   AMERICAN    TRADE   UNIONS 

When  a  local  union  of  the  Elevator  Constructors  is  forced 
by  the  employers  to  find  additional  workmen,  it  secures  men 
who  have  had  experience  in  elevator  construction,  or  struc- 
tural and  ornamental  iron  workers,  machinists,  carpenters, 
and  electricians.  The  work  is  of  such  a  character  that 
under  the  guidance  of  experienced  elevator  constructors 
these  workmen  of  closely  allied  trades  can  be  utilized  very 
satisfactorily.  But  these  men  are  not  required  to  join  the 
union.  Indeed,  in  the  greater  number  of  cases  they  are  not 
admitted.  They  are  given  "permits"  which  are  valid  for 
one  or  two  weeks.  If  their  services  are  needed  after  this 
time  the  permits  are  renewed,  but  if  employment  is  not  plenti- 
ful the  men  are  released.  For  these  permits  the  union 
charges  the  sum  of  25  or  50  cents  per  day.  The  rules 
of  the  Chicago  local  union  provide  that  "  when  the  condition 
of  trade  makes  it  impossible  to  furnish  employers  with  the 
necessary  help  from  among  the  regular  members,  the  busi- 
ness agent  shall  have  power  to  issue  permits  to  the  members 
of  other  trades  who  may  be  competent  to  do  the  work. 
These  permits  may  be  withdrawn  at  any  time  by  the  busi- 
ness agent."7 

President  Murphy  of  the  Elevator  Constructors  says  that 
in  1912  the  New  York  local  union  was  working  three  hun- 
dred and  fifty  permit  men  at  one  time.8  Nor  are  the  fluctua- 
tions which  require  additional  men  of  short  duration.  The 
secretary  reported  in  1908  that  the  Philadelphia  local  union 
had  had  an  average  of  twenty-five  permit  men  for  two 
months,  and  added :  "  now  that  trade  is  dull,  the  permit  men 
are  being  dispensed  with  to  make  room  for  the  regular  mem- 
bers who  are  out  of  work."9  When  asked  as  to  the  union's 
motive  in  using  the  permit  system  to  such  an  extent,  Presi- 
dent Murphy  stated  that  the  main  reason  was  the  desire  to 
maintain  the  number  of  members  at  such  a  point  that  all 

would  be  steadily  employed  throughout  the  year.10 

' .g. 

1  Constitution,  1914,  art.  8,  sec.  16. 

8  Interview,  August,  1915. 

9  Elevator  Constructor,  1908,  p.  23. 

10  Interview,  August,  1915.         , 


TRADE   UNION   THEORY   OF   UNEMPLOYMENT  39 

Partly  on  account  of  the  great  seasonal  fluctuations,  partly 
as  a  result  of  the  policy  of  equal  distribution  of  employment 
during  the  dull  seasons,  and  partly  on  account  of  the  fear 
of  prohibition  and  local  option  laws,  the  Brewery  Workers 
also  use  the  permit  system.11  During  the  summer  a  large 
force  of  extra  workmen  is  needed  in  all  breweries.  By 
reason  of  the  policy  of  the  union  respecting  the  restriction 
of  membership,  the  supply  of  workmen  is  not  sufficient  to 
cope  with  this  extra  work.  The  union,  which  has  practically 
complete  control  of  the  trade,  has  been  given  the  power  to 
designate  the  workmen  to  fill  all  vacancies.  Accordingly, 
the  union  secures  unemployed  members  of  other  unions,  gen- 
erally from  those  trades  which  experience  seasonal  unem- 
ployment during  the  summer  months.  The  character  of  the 
work  is  such  that  no  previous  experience  is  required. 
These  additional  workmen  are  given  permits  which  are  re- 
vocable at  any  time  on  demand  of  the  business  agent.  The 
fees  charged  the  permit  men  are  the  same  as  the  dues  paid 
by  the  regular  members. 

In  the  Flint  Glass  Workers  there  has  been  a  shortage 
of  mould  makers  on  frequent  occasions  since  1901.  Inas- 
much as  the  periods  during  which  a  scarcity  of  men  has 
existed  have  been  of  short  duration,  the  union  has  refused 
to  allow  the  employers  to  increase  the  ratio  of  apprentices 
to  journeymen.  As  a  substitute,  President  Voitle  of  the 
Flint  Glass  Workers  in  1902  advised  that  the  manufacturers 
be  permitted  to  employ  members  of  the  Machinists'  union  to 
do  patching.  Such  workmen,  however,  were  not  to  become 
members  of  the  union,  but  to  pay  the  regular  assessments  on 
their  earnings.  Furthermore,  the  permits  of  the  machinists 
were  to  be  revoked  not  later  than  June  30,  1902."  It  ap- 
pears that  this  proposal  was  not  adopted  as  a  general  rule, 
although  it  was  put  into  practice  in  several  shops. 

In  1904  the  manufacturers  again  complained  of  a  scarcity 
of  mould  makers  and  it  was  proposed  that  members  of  the 
Machinists'  Union  be  given  permits  to  do  this  class  of 

11  Interview  with  Secretary  Proebstle,  August,  1915. 

12  Proceedings,  1902,  pp.  60-61. 


4O        UNEMPLOYMENT  AND  AMERICAN   TRADE   UNIONS 

work.      President    Rowe   in    speaking   of    the   proposition 
said: 

"  I  believe  that  if  we  extend  relief  to  the  bottle-mould  shops  where 
it  is  badly  needed  at  the  present  time,  we  should  carefully  measure 
the  number  required  to  furnish  the  relief  necessary,  and  we  should 
confine  that  relief  for  one  or  two  years  to  the  common  grade  of 
work.  If  at  the  expiration  of  the  period  of  one  or  two  years,  we 
are  unable  to  fill  the  places  with  mould  makers  competent  to  do  the 
work,  we  should  then  teach  the  trade  to  the  machinists  with  permits, 
and  when  they  become  competent  workmen  we  should  admit  them 
to  membership.  I  favor  this  plan  in  preference  to  admitting  more 
apprentices.  If  we  admit  more  apprentices  we  will  have  them  on 
our  trade  at  all  times,  owing  to  the  fact  that  they  have  learned  no 
other  trade.  We  should  arrange  specifications  whereby  the  machin- 
ists could  be  put  off  in  case  of  slackness  in  trade  and  they  would 
have  another  trade  to  go  to  in  case  it  was  best  for  the  interests  of 
the  workers  to  have  them  put  off."13 

The  permit  system  was  put  into  operation  by  the  Flint 
Glass  Workers  in  many  factories,  but  it  was  not  until  1914 
that  a  general  rule  was  adopted.  The  convention  of  that 
year  made  the  following  provision :  "  In  the  case  of  a  short- 
age of  mould  makers  and  the  American  Flint  Glass  Work- 
ers' Union  is  unable  to  supply  the  men  within  a  reasonable 
period  of  time  .  .  .  the  shop  committee  shall  have  the  privi- 
lege of  drawing  labor  from  the  International  Association  of 
Machinists,  and  all  those  engaged  under  such  circumstances 
shall  pay  assessments  into  our  Union  and  comply  with  our 
rules,  with  the  distinct  understanding  that  labor  drawn  in 
this  manner,  if  working  at  a  time  when  work  becomes  slack, 
shall  be  the  first  to  be  laid  off  before  there  is  a  division  of 
time."14 

In  the  building  trades  the  permit  system  is  in  operation  in 
a  great  many  local  unions.  The  Bridge  and  Structural 
Iron  Workers  issue  permits  to  sheet  metal  workers,  metal 
lathers,  and  boiler  makers  when  there  is  a  scarcity  of  union 
iron  workers.  The  Carpenters  frequently  allow  so-called 
"  hatchet-and-saw "  men  to  work  on  permits  during  the 
busy  season  and  the  Plasterers  obtain  "  handy-men  "  to  aid 
them  in  their  work.  The  local  unions  of  Chicago  and  New 

13  Proceedings,  1904,  pp.  133-134. 

14  Proceedings,  1914,  p.  193. 


TRADE   UNION    THEORY   OF   UNEMPLOYMENT  41 

York  have  been  the  chief  centers  of  the  permit  system.  It 
is  common  knowledge  among  unionists  that  at  one  time  it 
was  extremely  difficult  to  obtain  membership  in  any  of  the 
building-trades  unions  of  Chicago  and  New  York. 

The  Steam  and  Hot  Water  Fitters  have  utilized  the  per- 
mit system  in  various  forms.  President  Short  of  the  Build- 
ing Trades  Department  said  in  1911  that  "the  conditions  in 
Chicago  at  the  first  of  the  year  were  such  that  it  was 
deemed  advisable  for  the  United  Association  of  Plumbers 
to  organize  a  local  union  of  steam  fitters,  as  theretofore  it 
was  impossible  for  a  journeyman  steam  fitter  to  obtain 
admission  into  the  organization  to  which  he  should  belong. 
Instead  of  being  given  membership  in  the  Steam  Fitters' 
Union  he  was  compelled  to  work  under  a  so-called  permit 
system.  His  permit  would  be  renewed  from  week  to  week 
and  a  certain  fee  was  charged  for  it."15  While  the  present 
steam  fitters'  local  unions  of  the  United  Association  of 
Plumbers  do  not  arbitrarily  refuse  to  admit  efficient  jour- 
neymen into  the  union,  they  do  use  the  permit  system  for 
helpers,  and  to  a  certain  extent,  for  journeymen.  When 
there  is  a  scarcity  of  journeymen  steam  fitters,  the  union 
issues  journeyman  permits  to  its  most  efficient  helpers,  and 
in  turn  issues  permits  to  handy  men  to  take  the  places  of 
the  helpers  who  have  been  temporarily  promoted.  Such 
permits  are  revocable  at  the  desire  of  the  business  agent. 
When  work  becomes  dull,  the  permit  journeymen  are  re- 
duced in  rank  to  helpers  and  the  permit  helpers  are  given 
their  release.  The  fees  charged  the  helpers  on  permit  vary 
from  25  to  50  cents  per  day,  while  the  regular  helper  pays 
only  $1.30  per  month.  A  business  agent  of  the  Steam  Fit- 
ters said  he  attempted  to  secure  each  season  as  helpers  on 
permit  men  who  had  worked  in  this  capacity  before,  and 
generally  the  men  who  have  worked  on  permits  return  the 
next  season  for  the  same  privilege.18 

A  great  part  of  the  jurisdictional  disputes  among  the 

15  Proceedings,    Building    Trades   Department   of    the    American 
Federation  of  Labor,  1911,  p.  37. 

16  Interview,  December,  1915. 


42          UNEMPLOYMENT   AND   AMERICAN    TRADE   UNIONS 

unions  is  directly  attributable  to  the  "  work  fund  "  theory. 
Each  union  strives  zealously  to  increase  its  jurisdiction, 
since  the  members  expect  thereby  to  increase  their  field  of 
employment  and  thereby  to  increase  the  per  capita  amount 
of  work  for  the  members.  But  the  unions  carry  this  idea 
further.  It  is  a  well  known  fact  that  a  great  number  of 
workmen  are  capable  of  working  at  more  than  one  trade. 
Such  men  would  be  able  to  greatly  decrease  their  periods 
of  unemployment  by  transferring  from  the  trade  in  which 
they  have  been  thrown  out  of  work  to  a  trade  in  which  they 
could  secure  work.  When,  however,  a  member  of  a  union 
attempts  to  transfer  either  for  a  short  period  or  perma- 
nently to  another  union,  he  is  compelled,  with  few  excep- 
tions, to  pay  the  same  initiation  fee  as  an  unorganized  work- 
man.17 Very  few  unions  allow  the  interchange  of  cards. 
The  only  exceptions  appear  to  be  the  reciprocity  agreements 
between  the  Bricklayers,  Masons  and  Plasterers  and  the 
Operative  Plasterers,  the  Western  Federation  of  Miners 
and  the  United  Mine  Workers,  the  Maintenance  of  Way 
Employees  and  Carpenters,  the  Carmen  and  the  Painters, 
the  Glass  Bottle  Blowers  and  the  Flint  Glass  Workers,  and 
to  a  limited  extent,  the  Ladies'  Garment  Workers  and  the 
United  Garment  Workers.  A  member  of  the  Commercial 
Telegraphers,  for  example,  is  not  recognized  by  the  Rail- 
road Telegraphers  although  the  work  performed  by  the 
members  of  both  organizations  is  practically  the  same,  and 
there  is  much  transferring  between  the  two  industries.18 

Those  unions  which  are  organized  on  the  basis  of  indus- 
try, instead  of  trade,  furnish  the  most  flagrant  examples  of 
this  situation.  The  work  of  the  members  of  the  Stationary 
Firemen  and  Steam  Engineers  is  the  same  as  that  per- 
formed by  some  members  of  the  Brewery  Workers,  the 
Western  Federation  of  Miners,  and  the  United  Mine  Work- 
ers. But,  there  is  no  permanent  interchange  of  cards  be- 
tween these  organizations.  A  member  of  the  Teamsters 
cannot  secure  employment  at  his  trade  in  the  brewing  or 

17  The  Bridgemen's  Magazine,  December,  1903,  p.  5. 

18  Interview,  August,  1915. 


TRADE   UNION    THEORY   OF   UNEMPLOYMENT  43 

mining  industries  until  he  withdraws  from  the  Teamsters' 
Union  and  joins  the  Brewery  Workers  or  Miners.  When 
one  considers  the  number  of  industries  in  which  the  average 
mechanic  works  during  a  year  it  is  obvious  that  the  indus- 
trial union  form  of  organization,  unless  some  change  were 
made  in  present  rules,  would  be  less  adapted  to  combat  the 
problem  of  unemployment  than  the  trade  union.  Under  a 
system  of  organization  by  trade,  a  member  of  a  union  is 
free  to  work  in  any  industry  provided  that  he  is  employed 
at  his  customary  trade,  but  the  field  of  employment  of  a 
member  of  an  industrial  union  is  limited  to  one  particular 
industry. 

From  time  to  time  in  various  unions,  some  of  whose  mem- 
bers have  been  capable  of  working  at  more  than  one  trade, 
or  in  more  than  one  industry,  there  have  been  campaigns 
for  reciprocal  recognition  of  the  cards. of  certain  unions. 
During  the  past  few  years  a  number  of  such  agreements 
have  been  made.  Some  unionists  have  gone  further  and 
advocated  a  Universal  Card  System,  under  which  a  union 
card  would  be  accepted  by  a  local  union  in  any  trade,  pro- 
vided that  the  initiation  fees  of  both  local  unions  are  the 
same.  The  chief  argument  advanced  by  the  promoters  of 
the  reciprocal  agreements  between  particular  unions  and  of 
the  Universal  Card  System  has  been  that  when  a  workman 
is  compelled  to  change  his  occupation  he  is  generally  in  need 
of  funds,  and  this  is  a  most  inopportune  time  for  him  to 
pay  an  initiation  fee.  Certainly  the  fact  that  he  is  com- 
pelled to  pay  a  new  initiation  fee  has  forced  many  a  work- 
man to  relinquish  the  hope  of  securing  employment  under 
the  jurisdiction  of  another  union. 

In  some  unions  there  exists  the  practice  of  granting  se- 
niority rights  and  privileges  to  certain  members.  Under 
this  system  when  employment  slackens,  those  members  who 
have  been  longest  employed  are  given  preference  by  being 
employed  at  full  time  while  other  members  are  laid  off. 
The  system  of  seniority  rights  exists,  to  a  certain  extent,  in 
many  unions,  but  only  in  the  Railroad  Brotherhoods  and 
in  the  Printers  is  it  in  general  practice. 


44         UNEMPLOYMENT   AND   AMERICAN   TRADE   UNIONS 

The  Typographical  Union  established  its  priority  rules  in 
1892.  These"  provided  that  the  oldest  competent  substitute 
should  have  the  first  vacancy  and  when  the  working  force 
was  to  be  decreased  such  decrease  was  to  be  accomplished 
by  discharging  first  the  person  or  persons  last  employed. 
Furthermore,  when  an  increase  in  the  force  was  desired,  the 
persons  displaced  should  be  reinstated  in  the  reverse  order 
in  which  they  had  been  discharged.19 

This  rule  has  been  attacked  from  the  outset.  The  objec- 
tions made  to  it  have  been  summarized  by  Professor  Barnett 
as  follows:  (i)  The  power  of  men  of  superior  efficiency  to 
secure  employment  in  preference  to  workmen  of  fair  skill 
is  greatly  lessened.  (2)  The  incentive  to  high  efficiency  on 
the  part  of  the  employee  is  lessened.  (3)  The  employer  is 
less  likely  to  pay  superior  workmen  more  than  the  minimum 
rate,  for,  if  they  leave  his  service,  they  must  begin  at  the 
bottom  of  the  list  in  some  other  office.  (4)  The  distribu- 
tion of  work  is  curtailed,  for  the  foreman  is  unwilling  to 
permit  inferior  men  to  "  sub,"  for  they  would  thus  acquire 
priority  rights  in  the  office.  (5)  The  mobility  of  labor  is 
decreased,  for  a  substitute  with  priority  rights  in  one  office 
cannot  accept  a  situation  in  another  office  without  losing  his 
rights  in  the  first.20 

The  defenders  of  the  priority  rule  claim  that  it  was  estab- 
lished to  guarantee  equality  of  rights ;  that  before  it  became 
effective  situations  were  given  out  regardless  of  the  seniority 
of  candidates  for  vacancies ;  that  under  it  a  situation  holder 
is  secure  in  his  position,  while  the  first  substitute  in  the 
office  is  assured  in  time  of  promotion  to  a  position  as  regu- 
lar ;  that  it  prevents  members  who  are  subbing  from  secur- 
ing situations  through  favoritism;  and  that  it  tends  to  re- 
ward long  and  faithful  service.21  At  various  times  there 

19  Proceedings,  1892,  p.  135. 

20  George  E.  Barnett,  "  The  Printers :  A  study  in  American  Trade 
Unionism,"   in    American    Economic    Association    Quarterly,    third 
series,  vol.  10,  no.  3,  p.  241. 

21  George   A.    Stevens,    "  The   History   of    Typographical   Union 
Number  Six,"  in  Annual  Report  of  the  New  York  Bureau  of  Labor 
Statistics,  1911,  Part  I,  pp.  529-530. 


TRADE    UNION   THEORY   OF   UNEMPLOYMENT  45 

have  been  efforts  to  abolish  the  system,  but  each  time  the 
attack  has  failed.  The  New  York  local  union  in  1908 
pointed  out  that  the  priority  rule  "has  had  a  fair  chance 
to  prove  its  merits  in  New  York  City  and  we  are  firmly  con- 
vinced that  a  continuance  of  its  enforcement  will  prove  dis- 
astrous to  the  Union."22 

It  appears  that  the  system  has  undergone  considerable 
changes  which  its  promoters  did  not  anticipate.  President 
Lynch  said  in  1911  that  "there  has  been  a  gradual  and  de- 
termined application  of  the  priority  rule  in  a  broader  and 
broader  sense  until  the  danger-point  has  been  reached,  and 
in  many  jurisdictions  it  is  not  now  a  question  of  competency 
which  determines  the  man  for  a  particular  position  but  a 
question  of  priority.  The  priority  law  has  been  in  count- 
less instances  a  great  protection  of  our  members,  but  in- 
stances are  also  on  record  where  priority  laws  have  been 
used  to  protect  the  incompetent  to  the  demoralization  of  the 
composing  room  and  to  the  discredit  of  the  local  union."23 

In  the  various  Railroad  Brotherhoods  seniority  rights  and 
privileges  are  in  effect.  The  men  are  classified  in  certain 
groups  in  order  of  seniority,  and  the  men  last  taken  on  are 
not  entitled  to  any  work  until  the  men  in  the  various  groups 
are  receiving  runs  totaling  a  certain  number  of  miles. 
Thus,  in  periods  of  depression  the  young  men  are  placed  on 
the  extra  list  and  receive  employment  only  after  those  with 
greater  seniority  rights  earn  a  certain  amount  of  money  per 
month.  This  system  has  led  to  considerable  discussion  in 
the  Brotherhoods,  but  the  older  men  appear  to  be  firmly 
entrenched  and  the  younger  men,  realizing  that  some  day 
they  will  have  the  same  priority  rights  as  the  older  men  now 
enjoy,  do  not  strongly  object.  In  some  cases  the  system 
has  led  to  gross  inequalities  in  employment.  Thus,  it  was 
said  in  1915  that  one- fourth  of  the  total  membership  of  the 
Locomotive  Engineers  were  "  extra  "  men,  and  that  during 
the  previous  seven  years  on  a  certain  division  of  the  North- 

22  Ibid.,  p.  530. 

"Reports  of  Officers  and  Proceedings  of  the  Fifty-seventh  Ses- 
sion, 1911,  p.  39. 


46         UNEMPLOYMENT  AND  AMERICAN   TRADE   UNIONS 

ern  Pacific  Railroad,  the  "  extra  "  men  did  not  average  over 
$75.00  per  month,  while  those  with  greater  seniority  rights 
averaged  $175.00  per  month.24 

Some  unions  have  gone  farther  than  acquiring  seniority 
rights  for  the  trade  over  which  they  have  jurisdiction,  and 
have  created  rights  in  subsidiary  trades.  Thus,  when  it 
becomes  necessary  to  reduce  the  number  of  locomotive  en- 
gineers on  the  engineers'  working  lists,  those  thus  taken  off 
who  have  been  promoted  from  the  ranks  of  firemen  in  any 
seniority  district,  may,  if  they  so  desire,  displace  any  fire- 
man who  is  their  junior  in  that  seniority  district.25  It  is 
said  that  during  the  depression  of  1914  one  third  of  the 
engineers  on  some  railroads  took  the  places  of  firemen,  who 
in  turn  displaced  "  hostlers."26 

The  American  unions  have  attempted  to  solve  the  prob- 
lem of  unemployment  also  by  the  adoption  of  policies  of 
another  kind,  which,  it  was  thought,  would  tend  either  to 
increase  the  total  amount  of  employment  or  to  distribute 
the  employment  over  a  greater  number  of  their  members. 
Such  policies  are  (i)  restriction  of  output,  (2)  shortening 
of  the  normal  day,  and  (3)  regulation  of  overtime. 

The  policy  of  restriction  of  output  is  justified  by  a  num- 
ber of  unions  as  a  method  by  which  employment  may  be 
increased.  The  desire  to  "  make  the  work  go  round "  is 
prevalent  chiefly  in  trades  which  experience  extreme  sea- 
sonal fluctuations,  and  where  the  output  is  restricted  in 
order  to  "  make  the  seasons  longer."  The  instances  of 
union  regulations  for  the  systematic  restriction  of  output 
are  not  very  numerous,  despite  the  fact  that  the  induce- 
ments to  adopt  such  policies  are  very  great.  Fifteen  years 
ago,  a  number  of  unions  provided  in  their  constitutions  for 
a  restriction  of  output,  but  only  a  few  have  maintained 
such  policies  to  the  present  time.  The  force  of  public  opin- 
ion and  the  increasing  disinclination  of  the  employers  to 
— 

4  Locomotive  Engineers'  Journal,  January,  1915,  p.  36. 

26  Chicago  Joint  Agreement  between  the  Brotherhood  of  Loco- 
motive Engineers  and  the  Brotherhood  of  Locomotive  Firemen  and 
Enginemen,  May  17,  1913,  art.  n. 

26  Locomotive  Engineers'  Journal,  March,  1915,  pp.  224-225. 


TRADE   UNION   THEORY  OF   UNEMPLOYMENT  47 

bargain  with  the  unions  that  openly  declared  for  restriction 
forced  these  unions  to  abandon  such  policies.  Two  of  the 
most  glaring  and,  perhaps,  most  important  illustrations  of 
restriction  of  output  which  are  sanctioned  by  the  national 
unions,  are  those  of  the  Printers  and  the  Machinists. 

The  Typographical  Union  prohibits  the  loaning,  borrow- 
ing, purchase  or  sale  of  news  matter  in  type,  linotype,  matrix 
or  plate  form,  or  of  miscellaneous  matter  or  cuts  in  small 
forms  between  newspapers  of  a  city.  Furthermore,  the 
loaning,  borrowing,  exchange,  purchase  or  sale  of  matter 
or  matrices,  or  cuts  of  advertisements,  by  one  local  news- 
paper to  another  is  prohibited,  except  that  when  the  matrices 
of  advertisements  are  furnished  by  one  local  newspaper  to 
another,  the  text  shall  be  reproduced  within  one  week  from 
the  time  of  publication  as  nearly  like  the  original  as  possible, 
made  up,  read,  corrected,  and  proofs  be  submitted  to  the 
chairman  for  inspection.27  This  rule  has  been  characterized 
as  "job  making"  of  the  most  despotic  sort,  and,  although 
some  justification  has  been  attempted  for  the  rule  which 
requires  the  resetting  of  advertising  matter,  a  great  many  of 
the  members  of  the  union  criticize  the  rules  on  the  ground  j 
that  the  only  reason  for  their  enforcement  is  the  desire  to 
"  make  work." 

The  International  Association  of  Machinists  in  1901,  pro- 
hibited its  members  from  operating  more  than  one  ma- 
chine.28 The  one-man-one-machine  rule,  however,  is  not 
operative  when  the  machines  require  no  special  skill  to  su- 
pervise them  or  are  double  machines.  This  rule  had  its 
genesis  in  an  unwritten  law  which  prevailed  in  the  trade 
before  the  organization  of  the  machinists.  And  indeed, 
many  employers  do  not  now  object  to  the  rule  when  it  is 
applied  to  establishments  which  make  large  machinery,  be- 
cause in  these  establishments  two  machines  cannot  be  effect- 
ively operated  by  a  single  workman.  However,  in  shops 
making  smaller  work,  the  rule  operates  as  a  restriction  of 
output,  for  often  one  man  is  capable  of  operating  more  than 

27  Constitution,  1915,  sec.  168. 

28  Constitution,  1901,  art.  22,  sec.  2. 


48 

one  machine.  Thus,  while  the  one-man-one-machine  rule 
of  the  Machinists  is  justified  in  a  great  number  of  cases, 
there  are  other  instances  where  its  operation  is  merely  a 
method  of  "making  work."  The  union  explains  that  the 
purpose  of  the  rule  is  the  physical  protection  of  the  work- 
man, but  it  seems  clear  that  this  is  not  the  only  motive.  An 
officer  of  the  union  said  in  1901 :  "  We  prevented  the  intro- 
duction of  the  two-machine  system  in  137  shops,  employing 
9,500  men,  and  it  is  safe  to  say  that  if  this  system  had  been 
introduced  the  force  of  men  would  have  been  reduced  one- 
eighth;  hence,  in  this  we  have  saved  the  positions  of  1,188 
men."29 

These  two  examples  are  by  no  means  the  only  instances 
of  restriction  of  output  in  American  unions.  Thus,  a  cu- 
rious regulation  of  the  Plumbers  for  increasing  the  con- 
sumption of  time  is  the  prohibition  upon  its  members  of 
"the  use  of  the  bicycle  and  motorcycle  during  working 
hours."30  A  business  agent  when  asked  for  the  justifica- 
tion of  this  rule  stated  that  "a  plumber  could  cover  twice 
as  many  jobs  that  way."  The  Baltimore  local  union  of 
Plumbers  prohibits  its  members  from  telephoning  to  the 
employer  when  they  are  "  out  jobbing  to  know  if  there  are 
any  more  jobs  in  the  neighborhood."31 

In  the  majority  of  trades  there  are  unwritten  regulations 
for  the  determination  of  the  daily  "stint."  And,  in  the 
greater  number  of  cases,  they  have  been  handed  down  from 
one  generation  of  members  to  another.  They  are  not  in- 
corporated in  any  constitutions  or  working  rules,  but  there 
is  a  tacit  understanding  among  the  members  as  to  what  con- 
stitutes a  day's  work.  Frequently  these  restrictions  exist 
to  the  same  extent  among  non-unionists  in  the  same  trades. 

However,  there  are  frequent  instances  where  local  unions 
have  formulated  definite  schedules  under  which  the  output 
has  been  restricted.  Thus,  in  May,  1899,  the  Chicago  local 

29  Eleventh  Special  Report  of  the  Commissioner  of  Labor,  1904, 
P.  143- 

10  Constitution,  1913,  sec.  125. 

81  Working  Rules  of  Local  Union,  Number  48,  1914,  art.  12. 


TRADE    UNION    THEORY   OF    UNEMPLOYMENT  49 

union  of  Plumbers  adopted  a  set  of  working  rules  which 
specified  the  amount  of  work  which  was  to  be  considered  a 
day's  work.  When  a  journeyman  was  working  on  lead 
work,  eight  wiped  joints  should  constitute  a  day's  work,  and 
"when  finishing  on  flats,  apartments,  hotel  or  office  build- 
ings, one  fixture  shall  be  considered  an  average  day's  work, 
except  in  the  case  of  laundry  tubs,  when  each  apartment 
shall  constitute  one  fixture."32  The  outcome  of  the  adop- 
tion of  these  rules  was  a  general  lockout  in  February,  1900, 
and  this  device  for  restricting  output  was  abandoned, 
although  President  Kelley  of  the  Plumbers  stated  that  the 
rules  were  formulated  in  order  to  prevent  "  rushing."33 

To  sum  up,  it  may  be  said  that  policies  of  systematic  re- 
striction of  output  do  not  exist  to  a  great  extent  in  Ameri- 
can unions.  Generally  speaking,  those  rules  which  are  in  I 
force  have  not  been  dictated  by  selfish  or  sectional  class  in- 
terests alone,  but  by  the  desire  to  prevent  a  speeding  up  of 
the  workmen  which  threatens  physical  injury.  It  is  not 
desired,  however,  to  minimize  the  importance  of  that  aspect 
of  the  problem  which  has  to  do  with  the  desire  to  "make 
the  work  go  round."  It  is  generally  admitted  by  unionists 
that  this  is  an  important  motive  for  the  maintenance  of  such 
policies.  The  ever-present  fear  of  being  thrown  out  of 
work  leads  the  workmen  to  reduce  output  in  order  to  make 
the  work  last  as  long  as  possible. 

It  is  very  doubtful  whether  restriction  of  output  affects 
to  any  extent  the  amount  of  unemployment.  If  restriction 
were  applied  only  in  seasons  of  depression,  such  might  be 
the  effect,  but  restriction  of  output  on  the  part  of  individual 
workmen  generally  occurs  in  periods  of  prosperity.  The 
employers  maintain  that  in  busy  times  men  work  at  a  more 
leisurely  pace  than  they  do  in  dull  times,  and  the  reason  for 
this  difference  is  obvious.  When  every  member  of  the  local 
union  is  employed  and  there  is  need  for  additional  work- 
men, some  workmen  do  no  more  than  is  absolutely  neces- 

32  Report  of  the  Industrial  Commission,  1901,  vol.  8,  p.  407. 
»» Ibid.,  p.  966. 

4 


5O         UNEMPLOYMENT   AND   AMERICAN    TRADE    UNIONS 

sary  because  they  do  not  fear  immediate  discharge.  On  the 
other  hand,  however,  when  only  two-thirds  of  the  trade  is 
employed,  the  other  third  being  idle  but  anxious  to  secure 
work,  the  workmen  who  have  employment  will  exert  them- 
selves to  do  all  they  can,  knowing  that  many  unemployed 
men  are  waiting  for  any  vacancy  that  may  occur. 

Closely  linked  with  the  policy  of  restriction  of  output,  as 
a  means  of  partially  solving  the  problem  of  unemployment, 
is  the  union  policy  of  decreasing  the  working  hours  of  the 
normal  day.  Unionists  and  unorganized  workmen  have,  at 
all  times,  demanded  the  reduction  of  the  hours  of  labor. 
While  the  unorganized  workmen  have  not  succeeded  as 
well,  the  unions  have,  to  a  very  considerable  extent,  secured 
the  eight-hour  day.34 

The  unions,  in  their  demands  for  a  shorter  working  day, 
have  developed  their  argument  along  two  lines.  For  the 
benefit  of  the  employers  and  the  general  public,  the  unions 
offer  as  exhibits,  the  case  of  those  members  employed  at 
hazardous  occupations  which  require  uninterrupted  atten- 
tion in  order  to  guard  against  physical  injury,  and  that  of 
the  workmen  employed  at  tasks  which  consist  of  perform- 
ing the  same  operation  several  thousand  times  during  the 
day.  They  depict  such  workmen  returning  home,  after 
working  ten  or  more  hours,  physically  exhausted.  They 
demand  for  their  members  such  working  conditions  that 
there  may  be  "  eight  hours  for  work,  eight  hours  for  rest, 
and  eight  hours  for  what  we  will."  It  is  argued  that  the 
increased  productivity  which  will  result  from  the  shortening 
of  the  working  day  will  more  than  compensate  them  for  the 
increase  in  the  hourly  wages.  On  the  other  hand,  the 
unions  frequently  offer  a  different  explanation  to  their  mem- 
bers of  their  desire  for  the  shorter  day.  They  are  told  that 
to  decrease  the  working  hours  is  the  one  sure  way  to  solve 

8*  Of  the  21,165  union  members  reporting  to  the  Wisconsin  Fed- 
eration of  Labor  in  1913,  11,552,  or  54.6  per  cent  had  secured  a  nor- 
mal working  day  of  eight  hours  or  less.  The  average  daily  working 
hours  for  the  entire  number  was  8^4  ("Labor  Conditions  in  Wis- 
consin," Second  Report  by  the  Executive  Board  of  the  Wisconsin 
State  Federation  of  Labor,  July  I,  1914,  p.  13). 


TRADE   UNION    THEORY   OF   UNEMPLOYMENT  51 

the  problem  of  unemployment.  Thus  President  O'Connell 
of  the  Machinists  said  in  1901 :  "There  are  150,000  machin- 
ists in  this  country,  and  an  hour  taken  off  their  day's  labor 
would  give  employment  to  16,666  more  machinists."35  Thus 
the  problem  would  be  solved.  The  average  workman,  who 
has  been  working  ten  hours  a  day,  appears  to  believe  this. 
He  thinks  that  if  his  normal  day  were  reduced  from  ten  to 
eight  hours,  his  output  would  certainly  not  be  the  same,  and 
thus  work  would  be  furnished  for  his  unemployed  fellow 
members.  This  aspect  of  the  question  makes  a  great  im- 
pression upon  the  workman.  It  is  said  that  during  a  dis- 
cussion of  the  eight-hour  day  at  union  meetings,  references 
to  the  opportunities  for  study  and  for  more  recreation  which 
a  shorter  work  day  would  bring,  result  only  in  a  modicum 
of  applause,  while  a  word  picture  of  the  horrors  of  unem- 
ployment rarely  fails  to  elicit  the  tumultuous  appreciation 
of  the  audience.36 

Such  illustrations  are  not  fanciful.  The  American  Fed- 
eration of  Labor  has  adopted,  according  to  an  expositor, 
the  principle  that  "the  movement  to  reduce  the  hours  of 
labor  is  not  to  shirk  the  duty  of  toil,  but  as  the  humane 
means  by  which  the  workless  workers  may  find  the  road  to 
employment."37  The  Plumbers  provide  in  their  constitu- 
tion that  eight  hours  shall  constitute  a  normal  working  day, 
and  explain  that  "  inasmuch  as  the  business  throughout  the 
country  is  insufficient  to  furnish  employment  to  more  than 
50  or  75  per  cent  of  the  journeymen,  and  recognizing  that 
by  reducing  the  hours  of  labor  it  will  have  a  tendency  to 
keep  more  men  employed,  the  Saturday  half-holiday  is  rec- 
ommended to  all  local  unions."88  President  Kelley  of  the 
Plumbers  in  1900  set  forth  the  union  theory  of  the  shorter 
working  day  in  its  barest  form  as  follows:  "When  our 
members  decrease  the  number  of  working  hours  of  a  given 
day  it  simply  means  that  more  of  them  will  be  provided  with 

35  Machinists'  Journal,  April,  1901,  p.  199. 

88  Isaac  H.  Mitchell,  "  The  Unemployed  Problem,"  in  The  Nine- 
teenth Century,  July,  1905,  p.  117. 

37  The  Bridgemen's  Magazine,  January,  1910,  p.  9. 

38  Constitution,  1913,  sees.  118-119. 


52          UNEMPLOYMENT  AND   AMERICAN    TRADE   UNIONS 

employment,  and  as  a  consequence,  as  we  relieve  the  market 
of  its  unemployed  surplus,  we  simply  provide  for  the  un- 
failing operation  of  the  law  of  supply  and  demand,  and 
through  this  means  make  possible  the  inevitable  demand 
that  will  be  created  for  our  Labor."39 

The  Painters  at  their  convention  in  1913  adopted  the  fol- 
lowing resolution :  "  Inasmuch  as  the  average  painter  is  em- 
ployed not  more  than  seven  or  eight  months  in  a  year,  and 
as  the  only  permanent  remedy  for  this  condition  lies  in  the 
proportionate  shortening  of  the  working  day,  we  instruct 
the  Executive  Board  to  do  all  in  its  power  to  put  into  sub- 
stantial effect  the  six-hour  day."40  Secretary  McGuire  of 
the  Carpenters  and  Joiners  as  early  as  1888  said  that  "by 
reducing  the  hours  of  labor  we  are  furnishing  employment 
for  our  unemployed"41;  and  the  Editor  of  the  Bridge  and 
Structural  Iron  Workers'  journal  probably  stated  succinctly 
the  union's  belief  when  he  said :  "  Trade  unions  shorten  the 
hours  of  labor  to  place  more  men  at  work."42 

While  a  great  number  of  trade  unionists  still  hold  this 
belief  in  the  effect  of  the  eight-hour  day  on  unemployment, 
some  of  them  have  changed  their  former  attitude.  In  1898 
President  Gompers  of  the  American  Federation  of  Labor 
stated  that  "  in  every  industry  where  the  hours  of  labor  have 
been  reduced  through  the  efforts  of  organized  labor,  it  has 
been  followed  by  these  results :  wages  have  been  increased, 
periods  or  seasons  of  employment  have  been  lengthened 
and  the  number  of  unemployed  has  been  reduced."43  But 
in  1915,  in  "The  Philosophy  of  the  Shorter  Working  Day," 
he  says  that  "the  individual  production  of  the  short-hours, 
highly-paid  worker  is  vastly  greater  than  that  of  the  long- 
hours  worker."44  If  this  is  accepted  as  true,  no  employment 
has  been  created  for  those  out  of  work.  Likewise,  the  atti- 
tude of  President  Duncan  of  the  Granite  Cutters  has  under- 

39  Proceedings,  1900,  p.  14. 

40  Proceedings,  1913,  p.  6^1. 
Proceedings,  1888,  p.  18. 

2  Bridgemen's  Magazine,  March,  1914,  p.  149. 

43  Leather  Workers'  Journal,  September,  1898,  p.  4. 

44  American  Federationist,  March,  1915,  p.  167. 


TRADE   UNION   THEORY   OF   UNEMPLOYMENT  53 

gone  a  considerable  change.  Writing  in  1909  he  said:  "It 
was  to  help  in  the  elimination  of  poverty  that  organized 
workmen  agitated  for  a  reduction  of  the  working  hours  per 
day,  and  the  fact  that  they  now  enjoy  a  shorter  work  day 
gives  employment  to  many  who,  under  the  old  method, 
would  be  idle,  and  each  person  so  employed  is  a  step  in  the 
trade  union  campaign  against  poverty."45  But  in  1914  he 
stated  that  the  reduction  of  the  hours  in  the  Granite  Cutters 
from  ten  to  nine,  and  then  to  eight,  had  neither  lengthened 
the  seasons  of  employment  nor  given  work  to  those  un- 
employed.** 

Trade  unionists  have,  in  the  past  few  years,  come  to 
realize  that  not  only  is  their  explanation  of  the  effect  of  a 
shorter  working  day  on  unemployment  false  in  theory,  but 
that  it  did  not  work  in  practice.  With  but  few  exceptions, 
the  officials  and  members  admit  that  the  eight-hour  day 
has  not  decreased  unemployment.  The  explanation  is  made 
that  the  individual  production  is  the  same  in  both  cases. 
President  Gompers  of  the  American  Federation  of  Labor 
has  stated  that  "  there  has  been  no  diminution  of  output  by 
reason  of  the  reduction  of  hours  from  ten  to  eight.  In  not 
a  few  cases  the  output  has  not  varied  from  the  results  of 
ten  hours,  the  number  of  human  workers  remaining  the  same 
in  proportion."47  It  is  only  in  the  building  trades  that  the 
workmen  still  claim  that  the  output  in  an  eight-hour  day  is 
less  than  under  the  ten-hour  day,  and  here  in  a  few  trades, 
especially  those  of  the  plumbers  and  the  painters,  it  appears 
that  this  is  true.48 

45  Bridgemen's  Magazine,  January,  1910,  p.  14. 

46  Granite  Cutters'  Journal,  August,  1914,  p.  2. 

47  Brauer-Zeitung,  March  25,  1911,  p.  I. 

48  For  an  account  of  the  results  which  have  been  obtained  in  sev- 
eral large  establishments  through  a  reduction  of  the  working  hours 
from  ten  to  eight  per  day,  the  reader  is  referred  to  a  most  instructive 
article,  "  The  Eight-Hour  Day,"  by  C.  J.  Morrison  in  the  Engineer- 
ing Magazine,  December,   1915,  pp.  363-366.     Mr.  Morrison  shows 
that  manufacturers  have  limited  their  working  day  to  an  eight-hour 
basis  without  diminution  of  output;  indeed,  in  some  cases,  more 
goods  were  produced  under  the  eight-hour  day  and  at  lower  costs. 
For  other  accounts  of  the  results  of  the  operation  of  the  eight-hour 
day,  the  reader  is  referred  to  Thomas  K.  Urdahl,  "  The  Normal  Day 


54          UNEMPLOYMENT   AND   AMERICAN    TRADE   UNIONS 

The  question  of  the  regulation  of  overtime  is  closely  con- 
nected with  that  of  the  shortening  of  the  normal  day.  When 
a  union  has  secured  a  reduction  of  working  hours,  it  is  ex- 
tremely reluctant  to  allow  its  members  to  work  overtime.  A 
member  working  overtime  is  looked  upon  as  receiving  em- 
ployment which  should  be  given  to  those  out  of  work. 
Thus,  President  Woll  of  the  Photo-Engravers  deprecates 
the  "unjust  practice  of  some  of  the  members  who  work 
excessive  overtime  while  others  are  denied  the  opportunity 
of  employment."49  The  Cincinnati,  Ohio,  local  union  of 
Bricklayers  and  Masons  explains  that  its  members  are  pro- 
hibited from  working  overtime  because  "  the  object  of  regu- 
lar hours  is  to  afford  work  for  as  many  as  possible."60 

In  order  to  discourage  the  employers  from  resorting  to 
ove'rtime,  the  unions  have  demanded  that  a  wage  rate  con- 
siderably higher  than  that  paid  for  work  performed  during 
the  normal  day,  should  be  paid  for  all  overtime.  Generally, 
"  time-and-half "  is  asked,  although  in  certain  cases  over- 
time is  paid  for  at  "  double-time."  A  few  unions  have  gone 
further  and  prohibited  their  members  from  working  over- 
time, except  under  certain  circumstances.  Thus,  the  Granite 
Cutters  provide  that  "  overtime  is  not  to  be  worked  except 
in  cases  of  emergency,  such  as  the  spoiling  of  breaking  of 
stone,  delay  in  quarrying  large  sizes,  where  a  stone  is  re- 
quired to  finish  a  building  or  where  an  accident  has  hap- 
pened."51 The  Metal  Polishers  prohibit  members  from 
working  overtime  unless  all  vacancies  are  filled,  and  then 
only  when  overtime  is  absolutely  necessary.52  The  Spinners 
prohibit  members  from  working  overtime  under  any  circum- 
stances.53 

The  emphasis  laid  upon  the  restrictions  on  overtirnejis_ 

in  Coal  Mines,"  in  the  Proceedings  of  the  First  Annual  Meeting  of 
the  American  Association  for  Labor  Legislation,  1907,  pp.  50  et  seq., 
and  to  the  American  Labor  Legislation  Review,  March,  1914,  pp.  106, 
107  and  pp.  117-119. 

49  American  Photo-Engraver,  October,  1915,  p.  469. 

80  Constitution,  1912,  art.  9,  sec.  9. 

61  Constitution,  1912,  sec.  95. 

52  Constitution,  1913,  art.  35,  sec.  8. 

68  Proceedings,  1913,  p.  9. 


TRADE   UNION   THEORY   OF   UNEMPLOYMENT  55 

a  means  of  increasing  employment  is  further  illustrated  by 
the  rules  of  certain  unions  which  provide  that  when  a  mem- 
ber works  overtime,  he  shall  at  some  future  time  lay  off  an 
equal  amount  of  time.  The  Printers  have  formulated  a 
rule,  known  as  the  "six-day-law,"  which  prohibits  its  mem- 
bers from  working  more  than  forty-eight  hours  per  week,  if 
a  substitute  is  available.  Should  a  printer,  through  inability 
to  secure  a  substitute,  work  a  greater  number  than  six  days 
in  any  one  week,  or  whenever  his  overtime  aggregates  eight 
hours,  he  is  forced  to  give  the  first  available  substitute  the 
opportunity  to  work  the  exact  number  of  hours  which  his 
accumulated  overtime  amounts  to.  The  local  unions  are 
allowed  to  specify  the  period  during  which  this  extra  time 
is  to  accumulate,  provided  that  it  is  not  less  than  thirty 
days.54 

The  Railroad  Brotherhoods  limit  the  mileage  or  earnings 
of  members  when  other  members  are  unemployed.  The 
engineers,  for  example,  who  are  on  "work-lists  "  are  placed 
in  one  of  three  classes,  (i)  pooled  or  chain  gang  freight, 
(.2)  extra  road,  or  (3)  extra  switching.  In  the  busy  season 
the  men  are  transferred  from  one  list  to  another  to  suit  the 
demand.  The  crews  in  each  class  are  given  runs  in  the 
order  in  which  they  arrive  at  the  terminal  from  previous 
runs,  and-^oTong^  as  the  men  in  the  various  classes  are 
securing  regular  employment  and  there  are  none  unem- 
ployed, they  are  not  limited  to  a  certain  amount  of  work. 
5ut  when  the  earnings  of  some  men  exceed  a  certain 
amount,  while  others  who  rightly  belong  in  that  class  are 
unemployed,  or  are  receiving  less  than  a  certain  amount,  a 
limit  is  placed  upon  the  individual  members.  Thus,  those 
in  pooled  or  chain  gang  freight  service  cannot  average  more 
than  three  thousand  miles  per  month;  those  on  the  extra 
road  list  are  limited  to  the  equivalent  of  twenty-two  hun- 
dred miles  per  month ;  and  those  in  extra  switching  service 
are  not  allowed  more  than  twenty-two  days  work  in  a 
month.  The  result  of  these  rules  is  that  whenever  the 

84  Constitution,  1915,  sec.  105. 


56          UNEMPLOYMENT   AND   AMERICAN   TRADE   UNIONS 

average  earnings  exceed  the  various  amounts  while  there 
are  members  unemployed,  a  sufficient  number  of  workmen 
must  be  added  to  the  list  to  bring  the  earnings  within  the 
proper  limit.65 

While  one  of  the  motives  for  the  regulation  of  overtime 
in  all  unions  has  been  the  desire  to  give  work  to  the  unem- 
ployed, there  has  also  been  present  in  the  seasonal  trades, 
the  idea  that  a  regulation  of  the  working  day  would  tend  to 
shorten  the  seasons  of  unemployment.  Especially  has  this 
been  the  case  in  the  building  trades.  President  Duncan,  of 
the  Granite  Cutters,  for  many  years  has  exhorted  the  local 
unions  to  abolish  all  overtime,  and  thus  force  the  employers 
to  give  up  the  custom  of  rushing  the  work  in  summer  in 
order  to  close  down  the  entire  plant  in  winter.56  In  the 
building  trades,  even  during  periods  in  which  there  are  few 
unemployed,  the  local  unions  are  generally  unwilling  to  have 
their  members  work  overtime. 

The  actual  results  of  the  abolition  of  overtime  in  lengthen- 
ing the  working  season  have  been  entirely  contrary,  in  the 
greater  number  of  cases,  to  what  was  expected  by  the 
unions.  The  unions  have  failed  to  understand  that  even  if 
less  were  produced  in  the  eight-hour  day  than  in  a  longer 
working  day,  the  natural  tendency  would  be  for  the  em- 
ployers to  increase  their  working  force  rather  than  the  length 
of  the  season.  In  the  building  trades,  for  instance,  were  the 
employers  unable,  through  the  shortening  of  the  normal  day 
and  the  abolition  of  overtime,  to  complete  their  building 
operations  in  the  customary  season,  they  would  be  forced  to 
employ  more  men.  And  inasmuch  as  all  of  the  building 
trades  mechanics  are  generally  employed  during  this  season, 
the  employers  would  recruit  their  forces  by  securing  work- 
men from  other  industries.  Such  workmen  would,  there- 
fore, be  thrown  upon  the  industry  in  the  majority  of  cases, 

and  would  have  to  be  taken  care  of  in  the  dull  seasons. 
. 

85  Chicago  Joint  Agreement  between  the  Brotherhood  of  Loco- 
motive Engineers  and  the  Brotherhood  of  Locomotive  Firemen  and 
Enginemen,  May  17,  1913,  art.  n. 

66  Granite  Cutters'  Journal,  February,  1914,  p.  4. 


CHAPTER   III 
LOCAL  UNION  EMPLOYMENT  BUREAUS 

There  is  a  great  need  in  every  industrial  community  for 
some  agency  through  which  the  demand  for  and  the  supply 
of  labor  can  be  adjusted.  On  account  of  the  seasonal  fluc- 
tuations of  trades,  the  variations  in  the  demands  of  indi- 
vidual employers  in  consequence  of  peculiarities  of  their 
markets,  and  the  continuous  changes  in  the  personnel  of  the 
working  force  of  each  business  unit,  there  is  at  all  times 
more  or  less  maladjustment.  The  employment  bureau  is 
justified  when  there  is  unemployment  due  to  the  inability  of 
employers  to  get  into  contact  quickly  with  the  unemployed 
who  are  capable  of  meeting  their  requirements. 

In  descriptions  of  the  existing  employment  bureaus  of  the 
United  States  the  activities  of  the  trade  unions  have  gen- 
erally been  omitted  or  given  minor  consideration.  This  is 
due  either  to  the  fact  that  the  proportion  of  workmen  who 
are  organized  is  small,  or  that  the  majority  of  the  trade- 
union  employment  bureaus  are  not  merely  employment 
bureaus.  Furthermore,  one  cannot  learn  of  the  activities 
of  the  unions  in  this  connection  by  a  study  of  their  litera- 
ture. Many  trade  unionists  when  asked  whether  their  union 
maintains  an  employment  bureau  will  answer  in  the  nega- 
tive although  their  particular  union  may  possibly  have  a  very 
practical  method  of  securing  work  for  its  members.  The 
difficulty  lies  in  the  fact  that  there  is  prevalent  the  idea 
that  an  employment  bureau  is  an  office  with  card  indexes 
and  an  attendant  who  is  entirely  occupied  in  registering  the 
names  of  the  unemployed  and  receiving  applications  for 
workmen  from  employers.  The  trade  unionist  thinks  it 
only  natural  that  his  business  agent  should  secure  work  for 
him  when  he  is  unemployed.  This,  he  considers,  is  one  of 

57 


58         UNEMPLOYMENT   AND   AMERICAN   TRADE    UNIONS 

the  principal  benefits  of  the  union,  but  he  does  not  term 
such  an  agency  an  employment  bureau. 

It  is  obvious  that  the  need  for  an  employment  bureau 
varies  in  the  different  trades.  In  those  trades  where  the 
period  of  employment  is  relatively  long,  as  in  the  printing 
trade,  the  glass  industry,  and  the  various  railroad  trades, 
there  is  little  need  for  local  employment  bureaus.  The  main- 
tenance of  a  business  agent  in  such  trades  would  ordinarily 
be  uneconomical.  The  business  agent  is  peculiarly  the 
product  of  the  building  trades  unions.  The  need  for  such 
an  official  is  great  in  these  trades  because  of  the  short  term 
of  employment. 

Inasmuch  as  the  local  union  generally  provides  for  bring- 
ing unemployed  members  into  connection  with  the  proffered 
employment,  the  national  unions  have  given  little  considera- 
tion to  the  question  of  local-union  employment  bureaus. 
The  only  exceptions  appear  to  be  the  Ladies  Garment  Work- 
ers,1 the  United  Garment  Workers,2  the  Lithographers,8  and 
the  Cigar  Makers,4  all  of  which  require  their  local  unions 
to  "establish  labor  bureaus  for  the  purpose  of  designating 
work  to  the  unemployed."  In  the  constitutions  of  the  local 
unions  there  are  seldom  found  any  provisions  for  the  main- 
tenance of  employment  bureaus  because  this  is  considered 
to  be  one  of  the  essential  functions  of  the  unions,  which  it  is 
unnecessary  to  particularize. 

It  may  be  said  that  the  average  member  of  a  union  in 
search  of  employment  secures  help  from  his  local  through 
one  or  more  of  the  following  sources:  (i)  the  business 
agent  or  secretary,  (2)  the  shop  collector,  (3)  fellow 
members. 

In  practically  every  organized  trade  there  are  some  local 
unions  which  provide  for  the  employment  of  an  official  who 
is  paid  a  salary  sufficient  to  permit  a  capable  member  to  give 
his  entire  time  to  the  duties  of  the  office.  Such  officers  are 


1  Constitution,  1914,  art.  12,  sec.  2. 

2  Constitution,  1912,  art.  13,  sec.  2. 
8  Constitution,  1913,  art.  n,  sec.  I. 
4  Constitution,  1912,  sec.  131. 


LOCAL   UNION   EMPLOYMENT   BUREAUS  59 

known  as  business  agents  or  secretaries.  The  maintenance 
of  such  an  office  entails  the  expenditure  of  a  considerable 
sum  of  money.  The  salaries  of  business  agents  vary  from 
$20.00  to  $50.00  per  week,  while  the  average  is  perhaps 
$30.00,  and  there  are  incidental  expenses  of  $5.00  per  week. 
A  local  union  expends,  on  the  average,  about  $1900  a  year 
for  a  business  agent.  It  is  obvious  that  only  those  local 
unions  which  have  a  considerable  membership  can  afford  this 
expense. 

In  a  few  cases  the  expense  of  maintaining  business  agents 
is  shared  by  the  national  unions.  Thus,  the  Machinists 
assist  local  unions  in  maintaining  business  agents  in  any  city 
"if  after  due  investigation  it  is  found  that  the  interests 
of  the  organization  warrant  the  expense."5  The  Pattern 
Makers  in  1913  assisted  several  of  its  local  unions  to  support 
paid  representatives,6  and  the  Blacksmiths  for  many  years 
have  subsidized  all  local  union  business  agents  by  paying 
one-half  of  their  expenses.7  In  the  Molders  the  expense 
of  maintaining  the  business  agents  of  the  twenty-two  Con- 
ference Boards  is  partly  met  by  a  subsidy  of  five  cents  per 
capita  per  month  and  in  some  cases  by  an  additional  sum.8 
The  Teamsters,  Metal  Polishers,  Brass  Workers,  and 
several  other  unions  help  to  defray  the  expenses  of  the  local- 
union  business  agents  when  the  unions  are  in  need  of  assist- 
ance. Frequently,  several  local  unions  of  allied  trades  no 
one  of  which  would  be  able  alone  to  support  a  business 
agent,  together  maintain  a  paid  representative.  This  occurs 
generally  among  the  building  trades  in  small  cities. 

It  is  found  that  the  majority  of  local  unions  which  main- 
tain business  agents  are  either  in  the  building  trades,  or  if 
in  other  trades,  those  of  large  membership.  In  1915,  320 
local  unions  of  the  Carpenters  and  Joiners  maintained  busi- 
ness agents.  The  Chicago  local  unions  had  29  agents,  while 
New  York  had  16,  Boston,  12,  and  Philadelphia  and  San 

6  Constitution,  1913,  art.  10,  sec.  i. 

6  Proceedings,  1913,  p.  14. 

7  Interview  with  Secretary  Kramer,  August,  1915. 

8  Constitution,  1914,  art.  20,  sec.  6. 


6O          UNEMPLOYMENT   AND   AMERICAN    TRADE   UNIONS 

Francisco  each  had  7.  In  the  Painters,  there  were  275  local 
unions  which  employed  business  agents,  the  Chicago  branch 
maintaining  15.  Of  the  760  local  unions  of  Machinists,  47 
had  business  agents.  Thirty-seven  of  the  345  local  unions 
of  Boilermakers,  69  of  the  118  branches  of  the  Bridge  and 
Structural  Iron  Workers,  23  of  the  35  local  unions  of 
Elevator  Constructors,  and  45  of  the  90  local  unions  of  the 
Pattern  Makers  also  employed  representatives  in  1915.  Of 
the  other  unions,  the  majority  have  business  agents  in  the 
large  cities  and  in  the  industrial  centers  of  their  particular 
trades. 

The  duties  of  the  business  agent  are  varied.  Generally 
speaking,  he  acts  as  treasurer  of  the  union;  he  visits  the 
different  jobs  to  see  that  all  those  working  at  his  trade  are 
"paid up"  members;  he  settles  disputes  between  the  mem- 
bers and  the  employers,  interprets  the  rules  of  the  union, 
and  acts  as  an  employment  agent.  Thus,  as  one  of  the 
duties  of  the  business  agent  of  the  New  York  local  union  of 
bookbinders,  it  is  provided  that  "he  (the  business  agent) 
shall  keep  a  record  containing  the  names  of  the  unemployed 
reporting  for  work  and  he  shall  find  where  men  are  wanted 
and  adopt  the  speediest  methods  of  notifying  said  members 
of  such  vacancies."9  The  business  agent  of  the  Baltimore 
local  union  of  bricklayers  and  masons  is  required  "to  use 
all  honorable  means  to  procure  work  for  the  unemployed 
and  to  visit  all  builders  and  contemplative  builders  and  en- 
deavor to  secure  their  work  for  the  members  of  the  union."10 

While  the  activities  of  business  agents  have  probably  re- 
ceived more  criticism  than  those  of  any  other  union  official, 
it  is  no  doubt  true  that  the  agent  is  of  great  real  benefit  to 
the  organized  workmen.  The  average  business  agent  is  a 
well-informed  man.  He  is  on  the  alert  at  all  times  to  secure 
employment  for  the  members  of  the  union.  While  his 
primary  object  is  to  make  every  job  a  union  job,  it  is  in 


9  Constitution,  1903,  art.  5,  sec.  6. 

10  Constitution,  1909,  art.  10,  sec.  7. 


LOCAL   UNION    EMPLOYMENT   BUREAUS  6 1 

consequence  of  this  desire  that  he  is  efficient  in  supplying 
employers  with  workmen.  His  primary  occupation  is  to 
learn  of  developments  in  his  trade.  He  knows  the  condi- 
tion of  every  job  within  his  jurisdiction,  the  prospects  for 
the  future  employment  of  his  members,  and  the  immediate 
chances  for  securing  work  at  each  job. 

Let  us  consider,  for  instance,  the  activities  of  a  business 
agent  in  the  building  trades.  In  the  morning  before  the 
members  begin  work  he  spends  an  hour  at  his  office  in  order 
to  take  care  of  any  employment  which  the  employers  may 
have  to  offer.  Then  he  spends  a  part  of  the  day  in  visiting 
the  various  buildings  on  which  his  members  are  employed. 
He  consults  the  employers  and  the  foremen  as  to  their  need 
for  workers.  He  secures  from  the  architects  a  list  of  pros- 
pective building  operations  and  visits  the  contractors  or 
owners.  Thus  he  learns  of  practically  every  opportunity 
for  the  employment  of  members  of  the  union. 

The  business  agent  does  not,  like  the  average  employment- 
bureau  official,  wait  for  employment  to  be  offered,  but  makes 
a  survey  of  the  field  and  applies  direct  to  the  prospective 
employer.  Furthermore,  he  is  far  more  efficient  than  the 
average  employment-bureau  agent  in  that  he  is  a  specialist. 
He  knows  his  own  trade  perfectly ;  he  knows  the  ability  of 
each  of  his  men  and  his  characteristics ;  and  he  appreciates 
the  peculiarities  of  the  employers  and  the  conditions  sur- 
rounding the  various  jobs.  He  considers  these  conditions 
before  he  recommends  one  of  his  men  to  an  employer.  On 
the  other  hand,  the  ability  of  an  official  of  an  employment 
bureau  to  cater  to  any  particular  trade  is  limited.  He  is 
forced  to  deal  with  more  than  one  trade  and  as  his  knowl- 
edge of  each  is  limited  his  selection  of  men  is  more  or  less 
haphazard.  No  amount  of  questioning  by  the  employment 
agent  can  produce  a  knowledge  of  those  peculiarities  of  the 
individual  workmen  which  the  business  agent,  through  long 
association,  has  discovered,  and  an  acquaintance  with  which 
is  so  useful  to  him  in  selecting  workmen  for  particular  jobs. 


62          UNEMPLOYMENT   AND   AMERICAN   TRADE   UNIONS 

The  Chicago  business  agent  of  the  Pattern  Makers  thus 
explains  why  employers  apply  to  the  union  for  men : 

"  The  business  agent  knows  his  men  and  can  furnish  a  more  satis- 
factory man  than  the  employer  can  hire  at  the  door  of  his  factory 
by  taking  men  as  they  come.  Our  members  in  their  application  for 
membership  to  the  union  and  every  time  they  send  in  an  application 
for  work,  must  state  in  the  application  the  class  of  work  that  they 
are  used  to  and  how  long  they  have  worked  at  that  class ;  besides, 
we  get  confidential  reports  from  other  sources  upon  the  special  apti- 
tude and  ability  of  our  members.  The  union  officials  claim  that, 
being  practical  pattern  makers  themselves  and  having  this  line  upon 
their  men,  they  are  more  capable  for  selecting  the  men  for  a  given 
kind  of  work  than  the  employers  themselves,  who,  while  excellent 
business  men,  are  not  practical  workmen.  We  give  them  the  best 
men  we  can  get  for  their  line  and  we  never  send  a  man  to  a  shop  to 
do  work  that  he  can  not  do,  if  we  know  it."11 

While  the  business  agent  spends  the  greater  part  of  the 
day  in  visiting  the  various  jobs  and  shops  where  his  mem- 
bers are  employed,  he  also  has  his  office  hours.  These  are 
known  to  the  employers  and  to  the  members  of  the  union. 
The  latter  generally  loiter  around  the  union  headquarters 
in  order  to  secure  any  employment  which  the  business  agent 
may  have  to  offer.  Some  local  unions  have  gone  further 
and  designated  certain  periods  of  the  day  during  which  ap- 
plications will  be  received  for  the  different  classes  of  work- 
men. Thus  the  Chicago  Bakers  and  Confectioners,  in  their 
1914  agreement  with  the  employers,  secured  a  provision  that 
all  bakers  must  be  secured  through  the  union's  employment 
bureau,  which  would  be  open  all  day.  But  "  steady  hands  " 
must  be  asked  for  during  the  hours  of  ten  to  twelve,  and 
"  hands  "  on  cakes  between  one  and  two  o'clock,  while  sub- 
stitutes were  to  be  had  at  all  times.  Because  of  the  fact 
that  the  employer  can  secure  a  competent  hand  on  a  few 
hours'  notice,  the  union  is  frequently  called  upon  to  furnish 
workmen.  The  employer  calls  the  business  agent  by  tele- 
phone and  asks  for  a  certain  kind  of  workman.  Generally, 
the  desired  man  can  be  found  among  those  waiting  about 
the  hall,  or  one  can  soon  be  notified  by  means  of  the  tele- 
phone number  which  each  man  on  the  unemployed  list  gives 
to  the  business  agent,  and  the  employer  is  furnished  the 

11  Regulation  and  Restriction  of  Output,  Eleventh  Special  Report 
of  the  Commissioner  of  Labor  (Washington,  1904),  p.  188. 


LOCAL   UNION    EMPLOYMENT   BUREAUS  63 

desired  workmen  within  a  short  time.  This  is  practically 
impossible  in  the  case  of  any  other  employment  bureau.  It 
has  been  stated  by  the  Chicago  employers  of  union  pattern 
makers  that  they  receive  their  men  through  the  union  as 
a  matter  of  choice  because  "  it  is  much  easier  to  telephone  to 
union  headquarters  for  a  man  than  to  get  one  in  any  other 
way,"  and  further  that  "the  union  does  try  to  send  a  man 
best  suited  to  the  needs."12 

It  is  obvious  that  the  ability  to  secure  a  workman  on  an 
hour's  notice  is  very  convenient  to  employers.  Consider 
for  instance  the  case  of  bakers.  When  the  shop  starts  to 
work  it  may  be  found  that  several  "  first  hands  "  are  absent 
on  account  of  sickness  or  other  cause,  or  that  it  is  necessary 
to  provide  for  extra  orders.  In  such  cases  the  employer 
requires  the  services  of  additional  men  within  one  or  two 
hours,  and  the  union's  employment  bureau  is  usually  able 
to  meet  the  requirement. 

But  the  business  agent  goes  further  than  merely  receiv- 
ing applications  for  men,  and  sometimes  adopts  ingenious 
methods  of  securing  employment  for  his  constituents.  He 
scans  the  want  advertisements  of  the  press  in  hope  that 
there  may  be  found  opening  for  his  members.  He  secures 
publicity  by  advertising  that  employers  may  secure  work- 
men from  him  on  a  few  hours'  notice  by  merely  telephoning 
to  his  office.  By  means  of  such  methods  many  odd  jobs 
are  filled.  Thus,  the  business  agent  of  the  Memphis,  Ten- 
nessee, Carpenters  and  Joiners'  local  union  reported : 

We  send  out  one  thousand  circulars  each  month  for  the  purpose 
of  refreshing  the  memory  of  our  clients  that  we  are  still  able  to 
furnish  them  mechanics.  It  is  one  of  the  good  features  of  this  office 
that  we  secure  a  great  number  of  small  jobs  from  merchants.  The 
merchants  themselves  are  pleased  with  this  arrangement  as  it  saves 
them  a  great  deal  of  trouble.  The  instances  where  our  members 
secured  employment  through  this  office  during  the  past  year 
amounted  to  twelve  hundred.  Another  point  worth  mentioning  is 
the  assistance  rendered  other  trades  by  this  office.  Frequently  we 
receive  calls  for  painters,  plasterers  and  men  of  other  crafts,  and 
as  it  helps  us  as  well  as  others  and  serves  to  make  this  institution 
more  useful  and  popular  we  are  only  too  glad  to  oblige  them  in 
this  respect.13 

12  Ibid.,  p.  189. 

13  The  Carpenter,  February,  1906,  p.  4. 


64          UNEMPLOYMENT   AND   AMERICAN    TRADE   UNIONS 

It  is  obvious  that  by  requiring  the  employers  to  apply  to 
the  union  for  labor,  the  union  makes  its  employment  bureau 
more  efficient.  Such  a  course  has  been  pursued  more  or 
less  successfully  by  the  Bakers,  Barbers,  Brewery  Work- 
ers, Deutsch-Amerikanischen  Typographia,  Lithographers, 
Photo-Engravers,  Flint  Glass  Workers,  and  Potters.  Of 
course  such  a  policy  can  only  be  enforced  where  the  union 
has  thorough  control  of  the  trade ;  but  where  this  method  is 
practiced  the  union  employment  bureaus  are  put  on  a  more 
business-like  basis. 

As  was  stated  above,  the  greater  number  of  local  unions 
are  not  financially  able  to  maintain  paid  representatives. 
Such  local  unions,  however,  frequently  appoint  one  of  their 
members  to  perform  the  duties  of  a  business  agent  during 
his  spare  time.  He  is  generally  the  secretary  or  president. 
This  official  receives  from  the  employers  applications  for 
workmen  and  confers  with  the  employed  members  as  to  the 
prospects  for  work  at  the  different  shops.  Frequently  there 
is  appointed  in  each  shop  or  on  each  job  where  members  of 
the  union  are  employed  a  member  who  is  designated  the 
"  shop  collector,"  or  in  the  building  trades,  the  "  steward." 
It  is  the  duty  of  this  member  to  represent  the  union  and  to 
acquaint  himself  with  the  prospects  for  employment.  Should 
there  be  need  for  additional  workers,  it  is  his  duty  to  make 
this  known  to  the  unemployed.  At  each  meeting  of  the 
union,  the  various  shop  collectors  or  stewards  make  reports. 
The  shop  collectors  and  secretaries  are  of  great  assistance 
in  securing  employment  for  members.  The  employer 
knows  that  by  applying  to  these  men  he  will  be  supplied 
with  the  desired  number  of  workmen  more  quickly  and 
efficiently  than  by  application  to  any  other  agency.  Further- 
more, these  officials,  like  the  paid  representatives,  are  always 
on  the  alert  to  discover  possible  places  of  employment  with- 
out waiting  for  applications  from  the  employers. 

Another  source  from  which  the  union  workman  receives 
aid  in  securing  employment  is  his  fellow  workers.  One  of 
the  duties  of  a  trade  unionist  is  to  procure  work  for  his 


LOCAL    UNION    EMPLOYMENT   BUREAUS  65 

unemployed  fellow  member.  Thus,  one  of  the  duties  of 
members  of  the  Brotherhood  of  Carpenters  and  Joiners  is 
"  to  assist  each  other  to  secure  employment."14  A  member 
of  the  Bridge  and  Structural  Iron  Workers15  or  Bricklay- 
ers and  Masons16  takes  the  following  oath:  "I  will  at  all 
times  by  every  honorable  means  within  my  power  procure 
work  for  members  of  this  union."  At  each  meeting  of  a 
local  union  the  president  usually  asks  the  following  ques- 
tions :  "  Are  there  any  members  out  of  employment  ?  "  and, 
"  Does  anyone  know  of  any  vacancies  ? "  Generally,  if 
there  are  any  situations  unfilled  they  are  made  known  to  the 
unemployed.  Indeed,  several  local  unions  provide  for  the 
fining  of  those  members  who  fail  to  notify  the  union  of 
vacancies  which  are  known  to  them. 

The  permanent  headquarters  of  a  local  union  offers  a 
place  where  the  unemployed  can  congregate  and  where 
those  who  are  working  can  assemble  after  working  hours. 
The  importance  of  this  feature  of  trade-union  life  must 
not  be  overlooked.  It  is  here  that  all  the  members  meet 
and  talk  over  the  conditions  in  the  trade.  Those  who  have 
knowledge  of  vacancies  gladly,  and  one  might  say,  proudly, 
convey  such  information  to  their  fellow  members.  Pros- 
pects for  the  future  are  discussed  and  the  trade  gossip  is 
canvassed.  The  usefulness  of  such  meeting  places  has  long 
been  realized  by  the  trade  unions.  As  early  as  1893,  the 
Bricklayers  and  Masons  advised  the  local  unions  to  estab- 
lish and  maintain  headquarters  which  would  be  open  to  the 
members  at  all  hours  of  the  day.17  During  the  past  ten 
years  other  unions  have  followed  this  example,  and  at  pres- 
ent practically  every  building-trades  union  and  the  greater 
number  of  other  unions  maintain  such  rooms. 

One  has  only  to  spend  a  short  time  in  the  headquarters  of 
a  building-trades  union  to  find  that  the  members  are  fully 
cognizant  of  the  local  employment  situation.  The  average 

14  Constitution,  1914,  sec.  3. 

18  Constitution,  1914,  p.  42. 

18  Constitution,  1912,  art.  12,  sec.  4. 

17  Proceedings,  1893,  p.  113. 

5 


66         UNEMPLOYMENT   AND   AMERICAN    TRADE   UNIONS 

union  carpenter,  for  example,  knows  of  practically  every 
job  under  construction  and  of  the  more  important  ones 
for  which  contracts  have  been  awarded.  Not  only  does  he 
know  the  name  of  the  contractor  and  general  foreman,  but 
that  of  the  foreman  whose  duty  it  is  to  engage  carpenters. 
There  is  no  doubt  that  this  lessens  the  work  of  the  business 
agent.  The  workman  does  not  ordinarily  wait  for  the  em- 
ployer to  apply  to  the  union,  but  visits  the  foreman  before- 
hand and  tries  to  obtain  a  job.  In  many  cases  this  is  done 
while  the  man  is  still  engaged  upon  a  job  which  will  termi- 
nate before  work  on  the  new  building  will  be  started. 
While  this  method  of  obtaining  employment  is  generally 
termed  "  calling  around,"  it  is  very  different  from  the  hap- 
hazard means  by  which  the  unorganized  and  unskilled 
workmen  secure  employment. 

There  exists  in  all  unions  the  custom  of  "  calling  around." 
Having  failed  to  secure  employment  through  the  union 
agencies  described  above,  there  remains  the  possibility  of 
applying  direct  to  the  various  employers.  In  some  unions 
this  method  is  facilitated  by  a  printed  list  of  shops  or  fac- 
tories in  which  union  members  are  employed.  Generally, 
the  business  agent  or  secretary  will  indicate  certain  estab- 
lishments at  which  there  is  the  greatest  chance  for  employ- 
ment. But  on  account  of  the  increasing  efficiency  of  the 
union  employment  bureaus  this  custom  is  gradually  disap- 
pearing. The  workmen  now  realize  that  when  the  business 
agent,  secretary  and  other  members  are  not  cognizant  of 
any  vacancies,  there  is  small  chance  of  finding  employ- 
ment. Consequently,  this  method,  which  was  at  one  time 
the  chief  means  by  which  workmen  secured  employment,  is 
rapidly  being  supplanted  by  union  agencies.  In  some  unions 
it  is  held  to  be  discreditable  for  a  member  to  ask  the  em- 
ployer directly  for  work.  Among  the  Hatters  it  is  the 
accepted  custom  that  a  member  looking  for  employment 
must  not  apply  directly  to  the  employer  but  get  another 
member  who  is  working  in  the  shop  to  apply  for  him.  Fore- 
men who  hire  hatters  in  violation  of  this  rule  are  liable  to 


LOCAL   UNION    EMPLOYMENT   BUREAUS  67 

a  fine  of  $25.oo.18    This  rule  also  obtains  to  some  degree 
among  the  Cigar  Makers.19 

The  methods  by  which  workmen  are  chosen  for  the  va- 
cancies which  are  reported  to  the  union  are  of  sufficient  im- 
portance to  be  mentioned.  There  are  three  usual  methods 
of  determining  which  member  shall  be  given  the  proffered 
employment:  (i)  place  on  the  out-of-work  list,  (2)  the 
decision  of  an  official,  (3)  the  drawing  of  lots. 

There  are  two  kinds  of  out-of-work  lists,  the  compulsory 
and  the  optional.  The  former  is  found  in  comparatively 
few  unions.  Under  this  method  the  names  of  the  unem- 
ployed are  kept  on  a  list  in  the  order  of  the  length  of  unem- 
ployment, that  is,  those  who  have  been  out  of  work  the 
greatest  length  of  time  are  placed  at  the  head  of  the  list. 
When  the  employer  applies  to  the  union  for  a  workman  the 
first  man  on  the  list  is  sent,  and  unless. the  employer  can 
show  that  this  man  is  unable  to  perform  the  work  he  is 
obliged  to  employ  him.  This  rule  is  found  in  general  prac- 
tice only  among  the  Miners  and  Brewery  Workers,  but  ex- 
ists in  a  great  many  local  unions  of  other  trades.  It  is 
obvious  that  such  a  custom  can  only  exist  in  a  strongly 
organized  trade,  and  where  there  is  comparatively  little  dif- 
ference in  the  skill  of  the  workers. 

The  'optional  out-of-work  list  is  in  general  use  in  a  great 
many  unions.  Upon  application  the  out-of-work  list  is  fur- 
nished the  employer  and  he  is  allowed  to  take  any  man  on 
the  list.  Of  course,  if  he  should  merely  ask  that  a  work- 
man be  sent  him,  the  man  longest  unemployed  would  prob- 
ably be  designated.  Such  lists  are  maintained  by  a  great 
number  of  local  unions  of  the  Metal  Workers,  Hatters,  Pat- 
tern Makers,  Photo-Engravers,  Bakers,  Printers,  Litho- 
graphers, Blacksmiths,  Machinists,  Coast  Seamen,  and  of 
some  national  building-trades  unions.  The  rules  governing 
the  out-of-work  list  of  the  Coast  Seamen  are  as  follows: 
The  man  first  on  the  list  is  given  the  first  chance  at  the 

18  Interview  with  President  Martin  Lawlor,  August,  1915. 

19  Letter  from  the  secretary  of  the  Tampa,  Florida,  branch  to  the 
writer,  Feb.  22,  1913. 


68          UNEMPLOYMENT   AND   AMERICAN   TRADE   UNIONS 

vacancy.  If  he  should  not  care  to  accept  the  employment, 
his  name  remains  on  the  list  in  the  same  order,  but  if  he 
should  be  absent  from  the  roll  call  three  consecutive  times 
his  name  is  removed  to  the  bottom  of  the  list.20 

The  second  method — the  decision  of  an  official — is  more 
widely  used.  Generally  when  an  employer  applies  to  the 
union  for  workmen,  he  specifies  certain  requirements,  or, 
as  occurs  in  a  great  many  cases,  he  asks  for  a  particular 
man.  If  he  asks  for  a  certain  man,  this  member  if  unem- 
ployed will  be  sent.  If  he  does  not,  the  business  agent  gen- 
erally chooses  the  first  man  he  can  find  who  is  able  to  meet 
the  requirements.  In  the  building  trades  if  the  men  are 
wanted  quickly,  those  loitering  in  the  meeting  room  are 
chosen.  In  trades  in  which  there  is  a  high  degree  of  spe- 
cialization or  if  men  with  certain  qualifications  are  wanted, 
the  business  agent  generally  takes  into  consideration  all  who 
are  unemployed  before  designating  the  man  to  accept  the 
employment.  It  is  obvious  that  where  time  is  not  impor- 
tant this  is  by  far  the  best  method  of  choosing  men.  In- 
deed, as  was  said  above,  it  is  in  this  respect  that  the  business 
agent  excels  the  ordinary  employment  bureau  officials. 

It  is  to  be  admitted  that  by  giving  a  union  official  the 
power  of  designating  the  person  to  fill  a  vacancy  a  fertile 
field  for  favoritism  is  opened,  and  disgruntled  workmen 
have  frequently  asserted  that  the  chances  for  securing  em- 
ployment depend  more  upon  being  a  friend  of  the  business 
agent  than  upon  ability  or  the  length  of  the  period  of  unem- 
ployment. On  the  other  hand,  if  the  comparative  periods 
of  unemployment  were  the  sole  guide,  much  of  the  value 
of  the  business  agent's  service  would  be  lost. 

The  third  method  of  choice — the  drawing  of  lots — is 
found  in  very  few  unions.  Where  practised  a  number  of 
slips,  on  one  of  which  is  written  the  word  "  job,"  are  placed 
in  a  hat,  and  the  members  draw  the  slips  to  determine  which 
one  is  to  apply  for  the  job.  This  custom  exists  in  a  few  of 

20  Letter  from  the  editor  of  the  Coast  Seamen's  Journal  to  the 
writer,  October  25,  1915. 


LOCAL   UNION    EMPLOYMENT   BUREAUS  69 

the  local  unions  of  the  Cigar  Makers  and  in  some  building- 
trades  unions. 

In  certain  building-trades  unions  no  choice  is  made,  but 
the  information  concerning  employment  is  placed  upon  a 
bulletin  board  in  the  union  headquarters.  It  is  considered 
that  by  this  means  each  unemployed  member  is  given  an 
equal  chance  to  obtain  employment.  Under  this  method,  it 
frequently  results  that  many  times  the  number  of  workmen 
desired  apply  for  work. 

If  the  trade-union  member  is  unable  through  his  union  to 
find  employment,  there  remains  the  possibility  of  securing 
work  through  application  to  state,  commercial  employers' 
and  philanthropic  employment  bureaus,  and  through  an- 
swering advertisements  in  the  newspapers. 

Since  1890,  when  the  State  of  Ohio  established  the  first 
state  employment  bureau,  twenty-two  -other  States  have 
created  such  agencies,  and  more  than  twenty-five  cities  have 
formulated  plans  for  aiding  those  out  of  work  in  securing 
employment.  Of  the  twenty-three  state  bureaus  more  than 
one-half  have  been  established  since  the  financial  depression 
of  1907.  Although  one  of  the  reasons  for  their  establish- 
ment was  the  desire  to  curb  the  evils  of  the  private  employ- 
ment bureaus,  a  historical  study  shows  that  they  have  been 
created  mainly  in  periods  of  industrial  depression.  These 
bureaus  appear  to  a  part  of  the  public  as  one  of  the  princi- 
pal means  of  increasing  employment  in  such  depressions. 
States  and  municipalities  are  urged  to  establish  employment 
bureaus  and  great;  efforts  are  put  forth  to  insure  their  suc- 
cess. Soon  after  their  establishment,  and  when  business 
conditions  improve,  interest  in  the  bureaus  dies  out  and  they 
either  become  merely  registration  offices  for  the  down-and- 
outs  and  the  unemployable,  or  are  abandoned. 

The  actual  results  of  the  public  employment  bureaus  have 
been  well  described  by  a  recent  investigator  as  follows :  "  In 
practice,  far  from  supplanting  private  agencies,  the  free 
offices  have  not  even  maintained  an  effective  competition 
against  them.  With  few  exceptions  their  operations  have 


7O         UNEMPLOYMENT   AND   AMERICAN    TRADE   UNIONS 

been  on  a  small  scale,  their  methods  unbusinesslike,  and 
their  statistics  valueless,  if  not  unreliable.  Four  States  and 
about  half  a  dozen  cities  have  discontinued  their  offices  and 
most  of  those  now  in  operation  are  constantly  on  the  de- 
fensive to  maintain  their  existence."21  Under  such  condi- 
tions it  is  not  surprising  that  the  trade  unions  have  not 
given  their  support  to  the  public  bureaus. 

President  Gompers  of  the  American  Federation  of  Labor 
traces  the  "persistent  and  widespread  promotion  in  this 
country  of  the  scheme  for  state  and  philanthropic  employ- 
ment bureaus  to  the  transatlantic  steamship  combination 
and  the  great  trusts."  He  says  further  that  the  necessity 
for  the  public  employment  bureaus  arises  mainly  when  the 
stream  of  immigration  is  directed  to  one  locality  or  another 
to  the  benefit  of  the  employers,  and  that  the  employers' 
profit  comes  through  replacing  union  workmen  by  non- 
unionists  and  through  substituting  foreign  cheap  labor  for 
unorganized  labor.22  President  Gompers  appears  to  think 
that  trade-union  employment  bureaus,  advertising,  and 
regulated  private  agencies  are  capable  of  supplying  suffi- 
ciently the  needs  of  the  employers,  and  finds  no  reason  for 
the  establishment  of  public  employment  bureaus.*3  The 
convention  of  the  American  Federation  of  Labor  in  1914 
refused  to  endorse  a  resolution  urging  the  creation  of  em- 
ployment bureaus  by  States  and  cities.24  President  Furu- 
seth  of  the  Coast  Seamen  stated  during  the  consideration 
of  the  resolution  that  the  existing  bureaus  have  been  a 
"never  ending  curse"  and  have  always  been  .placed  in 
charge  of  those  "  who  have  no  sympathy  with  the  struggling 
toilers."25 

The  attitude  of  the  American  Federation  of  Labor  to- 
wards public  employment  offices  is  not  unlike  that  of  the 
English  and  German  trade  unions  when  public  labor  ex- 

21 W.   M.  Leiserson,   "  Public  Employment   Offices,"   in   Political 
Science  Quarterly,  Vol.  29,  1914,  p.  29. 
22  American  Federationist,  July,  1911,  p.  514  et  seq. 
28  Ibid.,  July,  1911,  p.  528. 

24  Ibid.,  June,  1915,  p.  31. 

25  Proceedings,  1914,  p.  357. 


LOCAL   UNION    EMPLOYMENT   BUREAUS  7! 

changes  were  first  established  in  those  countries.  Grad- 
ually the  unions  in  those  countries  have  come  to  realize  that 
such  bureaus  are  not  inimical  to  their  interest.  Recently 
the  unions  have  been  granted  some  share  in  the  manage- 
ment and  have  accordingly  appeared  less  hostile,  though 
they  can  hardly  be  considered  even  yet  as  sympathetic. 

A  few  of  the  American  trade  unions  have  not  objected  to 
the  establishment  of  public  employment  bureaus.  The 
Printers  at  their  convention  in  1915  went  on  record  as  fa- 
voring them,26  and  the  Maryland  Federation  of  Labor  has 
recently  endorsed  the  movement.27  Indeed,  the  Superin- 
tendent of  the  Illinois  Free  Employment  Agency28  said  in 
1901  that  organized  labor  was  largely  responsible  for  the 
creation  of  that  bureau,  and  Superintendent  Dunderdale  of 
the  Boston  Free  Employment  Office,  states  that  "it  was 
only  through  the  influence  of  the  trade  unions  that  the  law 
establishing  the  Free  Employment  Offices  in  this  state  was 
granted."29  In  some  cases  the  unions  have  cooperated  with 
the  bureaus.  Mr.  Sears,  superintendent  of  the  Boston  Em- 
ployment Agency,  said  that  the  unions  furnished  the  bureau 
with  information  regarding  labor  difficulties  and  that  there 
had  never  been  any  trouble  over  the  bureau's  supplying  the 
employers  with  strike  breakers.30 

While  it  appears  that  the  public  bureaus  in  general  have 
been  of  little  value  to  skilled  workmen,  there  are  several 
whidh  have  done  very  efficient  work  during  the  past  few 
years.  Indeed,  it  appears  that  the  trade  unionists,  while 
criticising  the  utility  of  the  bureaus,  have  made  some  use  of 
them.  Thus,  the  report  of  the  New  York  City  Public  Em- 
ployment Bureau  for  the  first  twenty-nine  days  of  its  opera- 
tion shows  that  of  the  10,489  persons  who  applied  for  em- 
ployment, 364,  of  nearly  three  and  one-half  per  cent,  were 
members  of  trade  unions,81  while  the  Boston  office  of  the 

28  Proceedings,  1915,  p.  65. 

27  Proceedings,  1915,  pp.  63,  67. 

28  The  Bridgemen's  Magazine,  December,  1901,  p.  182. 

29  Letter  to  the  writer,  February  25,  1916. 

80  American  Labor  Legislation  Review,  June,  1915,  p.  284. 
"  Ibid.,  p.  281. 


72         UNEMPLOYMENT  AND  AMERICAN   TRADE   UNIONS 

Massachusetts  Employment  Bureau  reported  that  of  the 
10,707  persons  for  whom  it  secured  positions  in  the  first 
year  of  its  operation,  441,  or  more  than  four  per  cent,  were 
known  to  be  members  of  trade  unions.32  Of  course,  the 
trade  unionists  use  the  public  bureaus  less,  because  the 
chances  of  a  skilled  worker  obtaining  employment  in  this 
way  are  very  much  less  than  those  of  an  unskilled  workman. 

It  has  been  estimated  that  there  are  between  4,000  and 
5,000  commercial  employment  bureaus  in  the  United 
States.38  The  majority  of  these  have  as  clients  mainly  do- 
mestic servants  and  waiters,  and  to  a  less  extent  girls  and 
women  in  the  unorganized  trades.  Only  a  few  of  them 
profess  to  secure  employment  for  skilled  workmen,  while 
trades  which  are  highly  organized  are  rarely  supplied  by 
these  agencies  except  in  times  of  strikes.  The  trade  unions 
regard  private  employment  agencies  largely  as  strike  break- 
ing bureaus  and  the  activities  of  these  offices  furnish  consid- 
erable proof  of  the  soundness  of  the  unions'  contention. 
Moreover,  several  of  the  unions  have  experienced  consid- 
erable trouble  with  commercial  bureaus  even  at  times  when 
no  strikes  were  being  carried  on.  Thus,  the  Hotel  and  Res- 
taurant Employees  complain  bitterly  that  its  members  who 
apply  to  such  agencies  in  periods  of  industrial  depression 
are  not  infrequently  made  to  pay  exorbitant  fees  for  the 
promise  of  situations  which  do  not  exist.84 

The  majority  of  trade  unionists,  especially  those  in  the 
building  trades,  cannot  hope  to  secure  employment  through 
the  commercial  bureaus  because  the  few  jobs  which  such 
bureaus  have  to  fill  are  mainly  non-union ;  and  the  general 
trade-union  antipathy  towards  these  agencies  is  such  that 
they  would  be  used  only  as  a  lost  resort.  An  exception 
seems  to  be  the  attitude  of  the  Steam  Shovel  and  Dredge 
Men.  In  its  monthly  journal  there  generally  appear  the 
advertisements  of  some  twenty  railroad  labor  supply  agen- 

82  Quarterly  Publications,  American  Statistical  Association,  June, 
1909,  P.  522- 

83  Final  Report  of  the  Commission  on  Industrial  Relations,  1915, 
pp.  171,  172. 

84  Mixer  and  Server,  September,  1915,  p.  68. 


LOCAL   UNION    EMPLOYMENT   BUREAUS  73 

cies  in  the  West  and  Northwest.  The  secretary,  however, 
explains  that  these  agencies  do  not  charge  the  members  of 
the  union  fees,  but  merely  act  as  the  union's  representatives 
and  obtain  their  fees  from  the  employers.35 

Within  recent  years  the  employers'  associations  in  all  the 
large  industrial  centers  have  established  employment  bu-  • 
reaus.  These  are  supported  by  the  employers  and  work- 
men are  not  charged  fees.  Although  the  directors  of  these 
bureaus  claim  that  they  have  been  established  in  order  to 
supply  the  employers  with  workmen  at  all  times,  the  major- 
ity of  them  owe  their  origin  to  the  desire  of  the  employers 
to  establish  and  maintain  the  so-called  "  open  shop."  These 
bureaus  are  in  most  cases  not  active  except  in  times  of  in- 
dustrial strife  and  the  motive  for  their  maintenance  is 
mainly  to  secure  a  weapon  against  the  unions.  Conse- 
quently, except  in  a  small  number  of  cases,  the  trade  union- 
ist cannot  hope  to  secure  any  help  from  them. 

In  every  city  there  are  religious  and  charitable  organiza- 
tions which  attempt  to  find  work  for  the  unemployed.  The 
tendency  during  each  period  of  industrial  depression  has 
been  to  multiply  these  agencies.  Inasmuch  as  the  main 
work  of  these  philanthropic  bureaus  is  to  secure  work  for 
the  unemployed  who  are  not  capable  of  holding  ordinary 
positions  the  trade  unionist  is  not  likely  to  receive  help 
from  this  source.  Frequently  the  unions  have  protested 
against  the  wages  at  which  such  agencies  have  placed  their 
applicants.  In  one  case  during  the  depression  of  1914  a 
philanthropic  bureau  in  a  Mid-western  city  was  accused  by 
the  trade  unions  of  undermining  the  whole  scale  of  wages 
in  the  city  by  sending  men  to  work  at  cut  rates.36 

There  remains  for  the  workmen  the  want  advertisements 
of  the  newspapers.  To  unskilled  workmen,  professional 
workers,  and  domestic  servants  these  are  of  some  value,  but 
the  skilled  mechanic  and  trade  unionist  can  rarely  use  them 
to  any  advantage.  A  study  of  newspaper  advertisements 
as  a  medium  for  securing  employment  shows  that  the  trade 

35  Interview  with  Secretary  Dolan,  August,  1915. 

38  American  Labor  Legislation  Review,  November,  1915,  p.  545. 


74         UNEMPLOYMENT   AND   AMERICAN    TRADE   UNIONS 

unionist  is  seldom  offered  work  at  union  wages  and  hours. 
Advertisements  for  carpenters,  painters  and  other  building- 
trades  mechanics  are  frequently  inserted,  but  the  men  are 
generally  to  be  employed  on  non-union  jobs.  A  study  of 
the  "  help-wanted  "  columns  of  the  Baltimore  newspapers 
for  several  years  resulted  in  finding  less  than  a  half-dozen 
opportunities  for  members  of  any  trade  union  to  secure 
work  under  union  conditions. 

In  what  has  been  said  above  the  attempt  has  been  made 
to  show  the  superiority  of  the  trade-union  over  other  exist- 
ing employment  bureaus  as  a  means  of  connecting  the  unem- 
ployed with  employers  in  need  of  men.  Not  all  of  the 
unions  have  developed  their  resources  to  the  full  in  this 
connection  and  accordingly  the  members  of  many  unions 
are  forced  to  rely  upon  other  means  of  securing  employ- 
ment. 


CHAPTER  IV 
UNION  AGENCIES  FOR  THE  DISTRIBUTION  OF  WORKMEN 

In  the  same  way  that  a  workman  is  forced  to  move  in  a 
community  from  one  employer  to  another,  he  may  be  forced 
to  move  from  one  local  labor  market  to  another  because  of 
the  variation  in  the  demands  for  workmen  in  the  two  local 
labor  markets.  Although  a  number  of  trades  are  affected 
in  approximately  equal  degree  throughout  the  country  in 
periods  of  general  business  depression,  there  are  other  trades 
which  are  differently  affected  in  different  communities. 
Even  in  periods  of  industrial  prosperity;  the  variations  in 
demand  among  local  labor  markets  are  great  enough  to 
necessitate  the  transfer  of  many  workmen.  Given  the  fact 
that  there  is  a  scarcity  of  workmen  in  one  labor  market  and 
a  body  of  unemployed  in  another,  there  remains  the  prob- 
lem of  making  known  to  the  unemployed  that  there  are  op- 
portunities for  securing  work  elsewhere. 

Some  unions  have  considered  it  their  duty  not  only  to 
secure  the  employment  which  is  offered  in  a  community  for 
the  members  who  reside  in  that  labor  market,  but  when  the 
demand  for  labor  in  a  community  is  such  as  to  require  the 
services  of  additional  workmen,  to  procure  them  from  other 
places  where  some  of  their  members  are  unemployed.  In- 
asmuch as  the  methods  of  those  unions  which  have  at- 
tempted systematically  to  increase  the  mobility  of  labor 
cannot  be  successfully  classified,  it  is  necessary  to  describe 
separately  the  activities  of  the  several  unions. 

Owing  probably  to  the  great  local  differences  in  the  de- 
mand for  workmen  in  the  granite  industry,  the  Granite 
Cutters'  Union  has  probably  the  most  effective  method  of 
adjusting  inter-local  supply  to  be  found  among  American 
trade  unions.  During  the  past  fifteen  years  the  following 

75 


76         UNEMPLOYMENT  AND  AMERICAN   TRADE  UNIONS 

system  has  been  maintained :  When  a  local  union  is  unable 
to  supply  from  its  members  the  number  of  workmen  desired 
by  the  employers,  the  national  union  is  notified.  The  gen- 
eral secretary  immediately  sends  this  information  to  the 
local  unions  nearest  the  locality.  If  it  is  found  that  the 
man  cannot  be  obtained  from  nearby  local  unions,  the  infor- 
mation is  printed  in  a  "flier,"  with  generally  eight  or  ten 
other  such  announcements,  and  sent  to  every  local  union  in 
the  country.  The  information  concerning  each  opportunity 
for  employment  is  complete.  The  "flier"  gives  the  em- 
ployer, the  kind  of  workmen  required,  that  is,  granite  cut- 
ter, polisher  or  tool  sharpener,  the  class  of  work  to  be  per- 
formed, the  number  of  men  required,  the  working  conditions 
and  the  length  of  time  the  men  will  be  given  en  ployment. 
These  "  fliers  "  are  generally  issued  weekly,  but  the  period 
depends  upon  the  variations  in  the  demand  among  the  dif- 
ferent localities. 

Unless  the  distances  between  the  local  unions  in  which 
men  are  unemployed  and  those  in  which  men  are  needed 
are  very  great,  there  are  few  cases  in  which  the  employers 
are  not  supplied  in  a  short  time.  The  general  secretary, 
besides  notifying  the  trade  of  the  opportunities  for  employ- 
ment, also  occupies  himself  in  furthering  the  transference 
of  the  men  required.  Members  are  advised  to  telegraph 
or  write  to  the  employers  before  moving,  and  as  this  advice 
is  generally  followed,  only  the  required  number  of  men 
transfer.  The  employers  have  expressed  their  satisfaction 
with  the  system,  and  the  union  has  succeeded  in  materially 
shortening  the  period  of  unemployment  due  to  the  need  of 
transference  from  one  locality  to  another,  and  has  done 
away  with  a  great  deal  of  needless  and  haphazard  traveling 
from  one  city  to  another. 

The  system  of  inter-local  supply  among  the  Glass  Bottle 
Blowers  had  its  origin  in  the  introduction  of  the  bottle 
machine.  To  operate  the  machine  the  services  of  expert 
pressers  were  required.  The  union  did  not  have  control 
over  the  class  of  workmen  who  were  able  to  perform  this 


UNION  AGENCIES  FOR  DISTRIBUTION  OF  WORKMEN         77 

kind  of  work  and  therefore  established  an  employment 
bureau  in  order  to  satisfy  the  demands  of  the  employers. 
In  1903  a  member  who  was  an  expert  presser  was  appointed 
as  chief  of  this  bureau.  The  bureau  seems  to  have  given 
satisfaction,  for  President  Hayes  reported  to  the  convention 
in  1905  that  the  employers  had  been  furnished  with  HI 
machine  workers,  which  amply  filled  every  demand  for  men 
of  this  class.1 

Having  been  so  successful  with  the  employment  bureau 
for  machine  workers,  the  union  decided  to  render  similar 
services  to  other  members.  Accordingly,  all  unemployed 
members  were  requested  to  send  their  names,  addresses  and 
occupation  to  the  national  secretary.  The  local  union  secre- 
taries jMjjC'  manufacturers  who  were  in  need  of  men  were 
asked  TO  notify  the  union.  This  extension  of  the  bureau's 
services  has  been  a  distinct  success,  despite  the  fact  that  at 
times  it  has  been  impossible  to  induce  the  unemployed  to 
transfer  to  places  where  work  could  be  secured.  The  gen- 
eral secretary,  upon  receiving  a  request  for  men,  sends  tele- 
grams or  letters  to  those  upon  his  unemployed  list,  and  if 
this  fails  to  procure  the  required  number  of  men,  the  trade 
is  notified  by  means  of  circulars.  Also,  each  local-union 
secretary  reports  quarterly  to  the  union  the  number  of  fur- 
naces at  work  and  idle,  the  number  of  members  employed 
and  unemployed,  the  number  doing  "  spare  "  work,  the  num- 
ber of  men  required  and  the  number  of  men  available  for 
transfer.  This  information  is  classified  and  sent  to  the 
trade.  Thus,  there  is  available  at  all  times,  definite  infor- 
mation as  to  the  condition  of  trade  in  the  various  localities 
for  the  benefit  of  those  members  who  are  unemployed  and 
are  willing  to  remove  to  another  locality.  There  appears  to 
be  little,  if  any,  difficulty  in  inducing  the  local  unions  to 
notify  the  union  of  a  scarcity  of  workmen,  and  the  traveling 
members  are  generally  given  the  same  consideration  as  the 
local  members  when  there  is  work  to  be  had. 

Another  national  union  which  has  established  an  employ- 

1  Proceedings,  1905,  p.  23. 


78         UNEMPLOYMENT  AND  AMERICAN   TRADE   UNIONS 

ment  bureau  is  the  Flint  Glass  Workers.  The  demand  for 
men  in  various  localities  varies  so  greatly  in  this  trade  that 
sometimes  it  has  been  very  difficult  to  supply  the  employers 
with  the  required  number.  In  the  agreements  between  the 
union  and  the  manufacturers  the  latter  have  demanded  the 
incorporation  of  the  following :  "  The  union  agrees  to  ad- 
vertise for  men  free  of  cost,  and  to  do  its  best  to  place  men 
in  the  factory  when  needed."2  The  mode  of  procedure  is 
for  the  local-union  secretaries  to  furnish  the  general  secre- 
tary with  definite  information  as  to  the  number  of  men  re- 
quired and  the  number  of  members  unemployed.  Those 
who  are  unemployed  and  willing  to  transfer  to  another 
locality  file  their  applications  with  the  union.  The  em- 
ployers notify  the  chairman  of  the  shop  committees  when 
they  are  in  need  of  men  and  they  in  turn  inform  the  gen- 
eral secretary,  if  the  local  union  is  unable  to  furnish  the 
desired  number.  The  general  secretary  immediately  notifies 
those  on  the  unemployed  list  who  live  nearest  the  locality 
in  which  the  shortage  of  men  exists.  If  this  fails  to  supply 
the  number  of  men  required,  the  entire  membership  is 
notified  through  the  official  journal  and  circulars. 

During  the  past  few  years  the  union  has  experienced  con- 
siderable difficulty  in  supplying  employers  with  all  the  men 
needed  in  certain  branches  of  the  trade.  Especially  was  this 
the  case  with  mould  makers.  The  union  through  its  trade 
letters,  journals,  and  circulars,  and  through  correspondence 
with  the  local  unions  in  1910,  and  again  in  1912,  attempted 
to  reach  the  unemployed  and  induce  them  to  transfer  to 
localities  in  which  there  were  shortages  of  mould  makers. 
The  places  remained  unfilled  despite  the  activities  of  the 
union.  It  was  clearly  a  case  of  unprecedented  prosperity 
in  this  department  of  the  industry,  and  the  union's  methods 
were  not  at  fault.  In  the  other  branches  of  the  trade,  the 
union  has  generally  been  able  to  effect  the  needed  transfers. 
The  custom  of  writing  to  firms  in  different  localities  for 
work  became  so  general  and  produced  such  unfavorable  re- 

2  Circular,  Number  i,  August  7,  1914,  P-  2. 


UNION  AGENCIES  FOR  DISTRIBUTION  OF  WORKMEN         79 

suits  that  the  Lithographers  in  1906  ruled  that  this  method 
of  applying  for  employment  should  be  discontinued.8  As  a 
substitute  there  was  established  an  employment  bureau  under 
the  direction  of  the  general  secretary.  The  unemployed 
were  to  send  their  names  and  qualifications  to  the  bureau, 
and  the  local-union  secretaries  were  required  to  notify  the 
general  secretary  of  any  vacancies.  Those  first  on  the  un- 
employed list  and  living  nearest  were  to  be  notified  by  tele- 
graph to  apply  for  the  positions  or  to  notify  the  bureau  that 
they  did  not  care  to  accept  them.  Although  there  appears 
to  be  only  a  small  number  of  transfers  among  the  lithog- 
raphers, the  employment  bureau  performs  its  duties  in  this 
connection  very  adequately. 

The  Photo-Engravers'  Union  for  many  years  was  con- 
fronted with  the  problem  which  exists  in  so  many  trades, 
viz.,  the  acceptance  by  members  of  positions  in  other  cities 
without  consulting  the  business  agent  of  the  union  in  the 
locality.  There  might  be  a  sufficient  number  of  men  who 
were  capable  of  filling  the  positions  in  the  city,  but  the  em- 
ployer, for  reasons  of  his  own,  preferred  to  obtain  work- 
men from  another  city.  There  was  thus  an  unnecessary  and 
costly  movement.  The  convention  in  1906  established  an 
employment  bureau  at  national  headquarters  and  adopted 
certain  rules.  It  was  made  compulsory  for  members  to 
write  to  local-union  secretaries  before  accepting  positions  in 
another  city.  The  unemployed  were  to  register  at  head- 
quarters. Local  unions  were  required  to  notify  the  bureau 
of  any  vacancies  and  the  employers  were  requested  to  file 
applications  for  workmen.4  During  the  first  six  months  of 
the  operation  of  the  bureau  108  applications  for  employment 
and  109  applications  for  workmen  were  received.  The  sec- 
retary reported  that  the  greater  number  of  these  positions 
had  been  filled,  although  it  was  impossible  to  give  the  exact 
number  as  the  members  did  not  always  notify  the  bureau 
when  the  positions  were  accepted.  It  was  then  provided 
that  when  an  applicant  was  notified  of  a  vacancy,  a  blank 

3  Proceedings,  1906,  p.  193. 
*  Proceedings,  1906,  p.  61. 


8O         UNEMPLOYMENT   AND   AMERICAN    TRADE    UNIONS 

was  to  be  sent  him  to  be  used  for  notifying  the  bureau 
whether  or  not  he  had  accepted  the  position.6 

From  time  to  time  improvements  were  made  in  the 
methods  of  the  bureau  and  its  usefulness  was  increased.  In 
1912  President  Woll  reported  that  the  bureau  "continued 
to  be  of  great  benefit  to  the  members  seeking  employment," 
and  likewise  that  "employers  have  been  aided,  and  general 
satisfaction  has  been  expressed  by  all  those  who  have  had 
occasion  for  its  use."6  During  the  past  few  years  the  effi- 
ciency of  the  bureau  has  been  increasingly  higher.  Writing 
to  employers  for  positions,  advertising  or  answering  adver- 
tisements for  employment,  and  applying  to  other  agencies 
than  the  union's  bureau  have  been  discouraged.  The  em- 
ployers have  thus  practically  been  forced  to  make  use  of 
the  bureau;  and  they  have  expressed  complete  satisfaction 
with  the  manner  in  which  they  have  been  brought  into  con- 
nection with  possible  employees.  The  chief  reason  for  the 
present  efficiency  of  the  Photo-Engravers'  employment 
bureau  has  been  this  realization  by  the  officers  of  the  benefits 
that  the  union  may  derive  from  it.  As  President  Woll  said 
in  1915,  "  We  should  ever  be  ready  to  do  all  in  our  power  to 
furnish  union  help  whenever  required,  not  simply  because 
the  employer  wants  it,  but  because  it  is  a  good  business 
proposition."7 

The  Potters  also  keep  a  list  of  unemployed  members  at 
headquarters.  The  general  secretary  requires  those  who 
apply  for  employment  to  state  their  experience,  the  par- 
ticular kind  of  work  they  have  performed,  and  other  perti- 
nent facts.  When  an  employer  inquires  for  a  workman, 
the  secretary  is  able  to  give  him  a  list  of  those  who  are  able 
to  do  the  work.  The  general  secretary  states  that  the  em- 
ployers do  not  hesitate  to  apply  to  the  bureau  for  men,  and 
that  the  system  has  been  very  satisfactory  to  the  members 
and  the  employers  alike.8 

6  Proceedings,  1907,  p.  46. 

6  Proceedings,  1912,  p.  24. 

7  Proceedings,  1915,  pp.  23,  24. 

8  Letter  of  Secretary  John  T.  Wood  to  the  writer,  October  25, 1915. 


UNION  AGENCIES  FOR  DISTRIBUTION  OF  WORKMEN         8 1 

Through  weekly  reports  made  by  the  local  unions  of  the 
Pattern  Makers,  the  president  is  enabled  to  secure  definite 
information  of  the  state  of  the  trade  in  each  locality.  The 
local  secretaries  report  weekly  the  number  of  members  em- 
ployed and  unemployed  and  the  number  of  wood,  metal, 
and  plaster  pattern  makers  wanted  by  the  employers.  These 
reports  are  classified  and  sent  to  each  local  union,  thus 
enabling  them  each  week  to  direct  the  unemployed  to  locali- 
ties in  which  they  can  secure  work.  The  president  also  at- 
tempts to  supply  directly  the  needs  of  employers  from  the 
list  of  unemployed  members  which  is  kept  at  headquarters, 
and  telegraphs  to  those  of  the  unemployed  residing  nearest 
the  place  where  men  are  needed.  These  efforts  coupled 
with  the  activities  of  the  local  unions  adequately  cover  the 
field  and  in  the  majority  of  cases  the  employers  are  quickly 
and  efficiently  furnished  with  the  necessary  men.9  The 
Stone  Cutters  for  many  years  had  a  system  like  that  of  the 
Pattern  Makers.  The  local  unions  reported  to  the  general 
secretary  the  state  of  trade  and  prospects  and  the  -number  of 
members  employed  and  unemployed.  These  were  classified 
and  sent  to  the  various  local  unions.  Since  September, 
1914,  these  weekly  trade  reports  have  not  been  published, 
because  the  employment  in  all  localities  has  been  very  poor 
and  there  has  been  no  need  for  transfers.10 

Three  of  the  railroad  brotherhoods  have  attempted  to 
facilitate  the  movement  of  their  members  by  the  establish- 
ment of  employment  bureaus.  At  the  first  convention  of 
the  Locomotive  Firemen  in  1888  an  employment  bureau  was 
established  at  headquarters.  It  was  provided  that  the 
national  president  should  keep  a  register  of  the  applicants 
and  endeavor  to  secure  employment  for  them.  The  officers 
and  members  of  the  subordinate  unions  were  urged  to  inform 
the  bureau  of  all  vacancies  and  the  railroad  companies  were 
requested  to  apply  to  the  bureau  for  men.11  It  is  understood 

9  Interview  with  President  James  Wilson,  August,  1915. 

10  Interview  with  Secretary  Drayer,  August,  1915. 

11  Locomotive  Firemen's  Magazine,  November,  1888,  p.  809. 
6 


82          UNEMPLOYMENT   AND   AMERICAN    TRADE    UNIONS 

that  the  bureau  was  established  in  order  to  secure  employ- 
ment for  the  one  thousand  members  who  were  thrown  out 
of  work  through  losing  the  Chicago,  Burlington  and  Quincy 
strike  in  1888.  Since  that  time  it  has  performed  but  little 
service  in  securing  employment  for  the  members  of  the 
union.  President  Carter  says  that  it  has  been  unsuccessful 
for  the  reason  that  a  railroad  generally  refuses  to  employ 
engineers  and  firemen  who  have  secured  their  experience 
on  other  roads.13 

The  Railway  Conductors13  established  its  employment 
bureau  in  the  same  year  as  did  the  Firemen,  but  it  was 
abolished  after  a  few  years  on  account  of  its  failure  to  be  of 
service  to  the  unemployed.  However,  it  was  reestablished 
at  the  Detroit  Convention  in  191 3."  Acting  President 
Sheppard  said  in  1915  that  while  there  had  been  quite  a 
number  of  applicants,  the  bureau  had  "been  able  to  lend 
practically  no  assistance  to  the  members  searching  for  em- 
ployment," although  immediately  following  its  establishment 
in  1913  employment  was  found  "  for  several  members."15 
The  Railroad  Trainmen  in  1915  appointed  one  of  its  mem- 
bers as  chief  of  its  employment  bureau  in  Chicago  "  for  the 
purpose  of  advising  its  members  who  are  now  in  search  of 
employment."16 

Prior  to  1912  a  member  of  the  Bookbinders  who  wished 
to  travel  in  search  of  employment  was  compelled  to  write 
to  the  secretaries  of  the  local  unions  he  wished  to  visit 
before  he  was  allowed  to  apply  directly  to  the  employers  for 
work.  Because  of  the  failure  of  the  secretaries  to  reply 
and  the  spirit  of  selfishness  displayed  in  many  localities, 
this  rule  was  abolished  and  an  employment  bureau  was 
established.  It  was  provided  that  the  unemployed  were  to 
register  with  the  bureau,  and  local  union  secretaries  were 
required  to  notify  the  general  secretary  of  all  vacancies. 
Members  who  left  positions  were  to  report  this  fact  to  the 

12  Letter  to  the  writer,  October  19,  1915. 
Proceedings,  1888,  p.  237. 

14  Proceedings,  1913,  p.  748. 

15  Letter  to  the  writer,  October  16,  1915. 

16  Railroad  Trainmen,  March,  1915,  p.  40. 


UNION  AGENCIES  FOR  DISTRIBUTION  OF  WORKMEN         83 

bureau  and  the  employers  were  requested  to  apply  for  men 
when  they  were  needed.17  During  the  first  month  of  the 
bureau's  existence,  July,  1911,  a  number  of  members  were 
furnished  with  employment,18  but  the  local  unions  did  not 
notify  the  general  secretary  of  the  vacancies  in  their  juris- 
dictions and  the  bureau  was  abolished.19 

For  several  years  prior  to  1912  President  Lynch  of  the 
Typographical  Union  advocated  the  establishment  of  an 
employment  bureau  under  the  supervision  of  the  general 
secretary.  The  convention  in  1912  instructed  the  executive 
officers  to  formulate  plans  for  such  a  bureau,20  and  the 
following  rules  were  adopted:  (i)  only  members  of  the 
union  were  to  be  registered  5(2)  each  applicant  was  to  pay 
an  initiation  fee  of  $1.00;  (3)  requests  for  men  from  cities 
in  which  there  were  local  unions  were  to  be  endorsed  by  the 
local-union  secretaries.21  The  bureau  was  opened  January 
i,  1913,  and  several  hundred  dollars  were  expended  in  send- 
ing to  the  trade  advertising  pamphlets.  During  the  first 
six  months  of  its  operation,  62  members  registered ;  during 
the  next  year  there  were  79  applicants  for  employment, 
while  for  the  year  1914-1915  only  29  members  registered, 
and  of  these  it  is  thought  that  but  few  received  employment 
which  could  be  traced  to  the  activities  of  the  bureau.  In 
short,  as  Secretary  Hays  said  in  1915,  the  "employment 
bureau  has  not  proven  very  satisfactory."22 

In  1901  the  Leather  Workers  on  Horse  Goods  established 
an  employment  bureau  at  headquarters  with  three  branches. 
The  country  was  divided  into  three  sections,  in  each  of 
which  a  member  was  appointed  as  employment  agent.  Each 
was  to  receive  applications  from  the  unemployed  and  at- 
tempt to  transfer  them  to  localities  in  which  they  could 
secure  employment.  When  one  of  the  agents  was  unable 

17  International  Bookbinder,  June,  1911,  p.  238;  Ibid.,  August,  1911, 
P-  303- 

8  Ibid.,  August,  1911,  p.  282. 

19  Letter  from  Secretary  W.  N.  Reddick  to  the  writer,  November 
9,  iQiS. 

20  Proceedings,  1912,  p.  302. 

21  Typographical  Journal,  August,  1913,  p.  86. 

22  Letter  to  the  writer,  October  19,  1915. 


84          UNEMPLOYMENT   AND   AMERICAN    TRADE   UNIONS 

to  supply  the  demands  in  his  territory,  he  was  to  notify  the 
general  secretary  or  one  of  the  other  agents.23  President 
Balsinger  in  1902  said,  "  The  bureau  has  given  universal 
satisfaction,"24  but  the  three  sub-bureaus  were  abolished  in 
1903-"  Since  that  time  the  bureau  at  headquarters  has 
been  maintained  and  has  kept  a  list  of  the  unemployed  from 
which  the  requests  of  employers  have  been  supplied.  Sec- 
retary Pfeiffer  in  1915  said,  "We  have  met  with  little  or  no 
success  for  the  reason  that  it  has  been  impossible  to  get  the 
employers  to  cooperate  with  the  bureau."26 

So  far  we  have  mentioned  only  the  more  important  unions 
which  have  established  employment  bureaus.  Although 
those  which  we  have  discussed  are  the  only  national  unions 
which  really  perform  any  considerable  service  in  placing  the 
unemployed,  there  are  a  number  of  others  that  from  time  to 
time,  under  pressure  from  the  employers,  attempt  to  trans- 
fer the  unemployed.  In  this  category  may  be  placed  the 
following  unions:  Bakers,  Blacksmiths,  Bridge  and  Struc- 
tural Iron  Workers,  Elevator  Constructors,  Stove  Mounters, 
and  Typographia.  In  none  of  these  is  there  any  perma- 
nent system  of  finding  employment,  the  unions  merely  at- 
tempting to  transfer  members  when  some  employer  or  local 
union  writes  for  workmen. 

Several  unions  have  emphatically  rejected  the  proposal 
to  establish  employment  bureaus  to  which  the  local  unions 
would  have  been  required  to  report  regularly  the  exact  con- 
dition of  trade.  Thus,  in  1895,  the  Iron,  Steel  and  Tin 
Workers  refused  to  accede  to  the  suggestion  of  President 
Garland  that  an  employment  bureau  should  be  established, 
to  which  the  local  unions  should  report  every  two  weeks 
as  to  the  condition  of  trade.27  The  general  antipathy  ex- 
hibited by  the  average  member  of  a  union  towards  any  pub- 
licity of  employment  conditions  is  probably  best  illustrated 
by  the  history  of  the  Bricklayers  and  Masons.  In  1873  a 

23  Leather  Workers'  Journal,  November,  1901,  p.  60. 

24  Ibid.,  July,  1902,  p.  306. 

25  Ibid.,  March,  1003,  p.  32. 

20  Letter  to  the  writer,  October  19,  1915. 
27  Proceedings,  1895,  p.  4940. 


UNION  AGENCIES  FOR  DISTRIBUTION  OF  WORKMEN         85 

national  employment  bureau  was  established.  Each  local 
union  secretary  was  required  to  inform  the  general  secre- 
tary monthly  as  to  the  number  of  employed  and  unemployed, 
and  whether  or  not  any  additional  men  were  needed.28  The 
bureau  lasted  but  a  few  months,  the  local  unions  refusing 
to  notify  the  secretary  of  the  actual  conditions  of  trade.  In 
1881  the  union  attempted  to  reestablish  the  employment 
bureau  and  at  this  time  required  only  quarterly  reports 
from  the  local  unions.29  In  the  following  year  many  of  the 
local  unions  refusing  to  report,  the  rules  were  changed  so 
as  to  require  only  semi-annual  reports.30  During  1905  Sec- 
retary Dobson  was  requested  by  employers  in  many  cities 
to  supply  them  with  additional  men.  He  thereupon  wrote 
to  all  local  unions  asking  them  to  report  the  actual  condi- 
tion of  trade,  giving  the  number  of  additional  men  required 
or  the  number  of  members  unemployed.  Only  a  few  re- 
sponses were  made  and  the  majority  of  these  were  from 
cities  in  which  employment  was  very  poor.  In  commenting 
upon  the  refusal  of  the  local  unions  to  give  publicity  to  trade 
conditions,  he  said :  "  Judging  from  the  replies  we  received 
we  understood  that  no  matter  how  many  men  were  needed 
to  supply  the  demands  of  the  employers  our  local  unions  did 
not  take  kindly  to  our  idea  or  desire  the  fact  to  be  known 
that  their  particular  communities  were  in  need  of  men."31 
There  was  an  attempt  made  at  the  convention  in  1910  again 
to  establish  an  employment  bureau  at  headquarters,  but  only 
one  third  of  the  delegates  voted  in  favor  of  the  proposal.32 
During  1912  Secretary  Dobson  once  more  tried  to  obtain 
from  the  local  unions  accurate  information  concerning  the 
state  of  trade,  but  he  was  forced  to  abandon  the  idea  be- 
cause the  local  unions  refused  to  supply  him  with  the  neces- 
sary information.33 

28  Proceedings,  1873,  p.  25. 
28  Proceedings,  1881,  p.  25. 

80  Proceedings,  1882,  p.  32. 

81  Fortieth  Annual  Report  of  the  President  and  Secretary,  1905, 
P-  334- 

1  Proceedings,  1910,  p.  169. 
83  Interview,  August,  1915. 


86          UNEMPLOYMENT   AND   AMERICAN    TRADE   UNIONS 

About  ninety  per  cent  of  the  American  trade  unions  pub- 
lish weekly  or  monthly  journals  which  in  a  number  of 
unions  are  set  free  to  each  member.  Some  of  the  unions, 
realizing  the  possibilities  of  these  journals  as  a  means  of 
conveying  information  respecting  employment  conditions 
have  utilized  them  for  this  purpose.  For  example,  the 
Cigar  Makers,  Iron  Holders,  Plasterers,  and  Sheet  Metal 
Workers  publish  every  month  in  their  journals  the  state  of 
trade  in  each  of  their  local  unions.  The  Woodcarvers' 
Journal  contains  reports  from  the  local  unions  giving  the 
number  of  shops  in  which  trade  is  good,  fair  and  dull,  and 
the  number  of  members  employed  and  unemployed.  The 
Bricklayers  and  Masons,  Carpenters,  Flint  Glass  Workers, 
and  Plumbers  publish  lists  of  cities  in  which  trade  is  dull. 

Some  of  the  building-trades  unions  have  for  many  years 
given  considerable  space  in  their  journals  to  construction 
news  in  various  cities.  Lists  of  the  principal  contracts 
which  have  been  awarded  and  advanced  information  rela- 
tive to  proposed  buildings  are  published.  The  Bridge  and 
Structural  Iron  Workers'  journal  contains  a  list  of  all  iron 
and  steel  buildings  and  bridges  that  are  contemplated,  and 
the  Bricklayers  and  Masons  and  the  Lathers  publish  news 
concerning  all  construction  work  that  will  give  employment 
to  their  members.  While  this  information  is  sometimes  val- 
uable to  those  who  wish  employment,  these  lists  have  in 
many  cases  caused  needless  traveling.  A  bricklayer  notic- 
ing in  the  journal  that  several  large  contracts  have  been 
awarded  in  a  distant  city  may  not  know  whether  the  con- 
struction is  to  be  of  brick,  or  whether  the  general  condition 
of  trade  in  the  particular  city  is  such  that  additional  men 
will  be  required.  There  have  been  many  complaints  in  the 
Bricklayers'  Union  concerning  the  publication  of  news  of 
this  kind,  and  at  times  the  journal  has  discontinued  pub- 
lishing it.  The  Stone  Cutters'  Journal  for  several  years 
contained  a  list  of  contracts  awarded,  but  discontinued  its 
publication  in  May,  1915.  Secretary  Drayer  said  that  much 
needless  traveling  had  been  caused  by  the  publication  of 


UNION  AGENCIES  FOR  DISTRIBUTION  OF  WORKMEN         87 

these  lists  since  members  had  transferred  to  cities  in  which 
the  journal  had  noted  great  building  activity,  only  to  find 
that  on  some  of  the  large  buildings  not  more  than  a  few 
hundred  dollars  worth  of  stone  was  to  be  used,  and  in  some 
cases  that  terra  cotta  had  been  substituted  entirely  for 
stone.3* 

The  Boot  and  Shoe  Workers,  Coopers,  Garment  Work- 
ers, Granite  Cutters,  and  Leather  Workers  on  Horse  Goods 
publish  the  names  and  addresses  of  employers  who  conduct 
strictly  union  establishments,  and  do  not  prohibit  their 
members  from  writing  to  employers  for  employment. 

In  all  trade-union  journals  there  is  a  great  amount  of 
correspondence  from  the  local-union  secretaries  and  busi- 
ness agents.  In  those  unions  which  have  a  relatively  small 
number  of  local  unions  there  is  opportunity  for  all  localities 
to  be  represented,  but  in  some  of  the  larger  building-trades 
unions,  for  example,  the  Carpenters,  Painters,  and  Brick- 
layers and  Masons,  this  is  not  feasible.  These  reports  from 
the  local  unions  generally  contain  information  as  to  the  state 
of  trade,  the  number  of  members  employed  and  unemployed 
and  the  prospects  for  employment.  In  some  cases  this  cor- 
respondence is  very  valuable  to  the  members  who  wish  to 
secure  employment.  Among  the  journals  which  serve  the 
purpose  very  well,  those  of  the  following  unions  may  be 
cited:  Photo-Engravers,  Bookbinders,  Printers,  Flint  Glass 
Workers,  Granite  Cutters,  and  Bridge  and  Structural  Iron 
Workers.  For  the  information  of  those  members  who  may 
desire  to  write  to  the  business  agent  or  secretary  of  a  local 
union  as  to  the  chances  for  employment  in  other  localities, 
32  of  the  80  trade-union  journals  print  lists  of  local-union 
secretaries  and  business  agents  with  their  addresses. 

Several  of  the  subdivisions  of  the  national  unions,  such 
as  state  conferences  and  districts  councils,  have  attempted 
to  devise  means  by  which  information  concerning  the  state 
of  trade  could  be  conveyed  to  the  unemployed.  Among  the 
building-trades  unions,  conferences  are  formed  in  the  vari- 

34  Stone  Cutters'  Journal,  May,  1915,  p.  I. 


88          UNEMPLOYMENT   AND   AMERICAN   TRADE   UNIONS 

ous  States,  composed  of  the  local  unions.  The  Bricklayers 
and  Masons  have  25  such  conferences,  while  the  Painters 
have  17  and  the  Carpenters  10.  The  Texas  State  Council 
of  Carpenters  sends  to  each  of  its  members  a  monthly  report 
of  the  number  employed  and  unemployed,  the  prospects  for 
employment,  and  the  number  of  men  wanted  in  each  local 
union.85  The  Massachusetts  State  Conference  of  Brick- 
layers and  Masons  also  publishes  monthly  reports  of  the 
condition  of  trade  in  each  local  union.36 

Some  of  the  districts  of  the  unions  have  gone  further  than 
simply  publishing  the  condition  of  trade,  and  have  estab- 
lished employment  bureaus.  Thus,  the  New  England  Typo- 
graphical Union  and  the  Indiana  Typographical  Conference 
have  conducted  employment  bureaus  for  several  years,  and 
President  Lynch  of  the  Printers  says  they  have  produced 
results  "to  the  satisfaction  of  affiliated  unions  and  their 
members."37  The  district  vice-presidents  of  the  Lithog- 
raphers receive  applications  for  employment  and  requests 
from  the  employers  for  workmen.  Vice-President  Lawrence 
reported  that  in  1906  he  had  succeeded  in  supplying  the  em- 
ployers in  his  district  with  workmen  from  the  five  hundred 
applications  which  he  had  received  during  the  year  from 
unemployed  members.38  Frequently  several  local  unions  of 
a  trade  will  conduct  an  employment  bureau  in  common. 
Thus  in  1915  the  railroad  divisions  of  the  Sheet  Metal 
Workers  established  an  employment  bureau  in  St.  Louis, 
Missouri.39  This  practise  exists  to  a  certain  extent  among 
the  pattern  makers  and  in  some  other  unions.  It  may  be 
said  that  while  these  subdivisions  of  the  unions  do  not  gen- 
erally cooperate  very  readily  with  one  another  in  employ- 
ment matters,  they  serve  in  some  degree  by  their  connec- 
tions to  direct  the  unemployed  to  localities  in  which  work 
can  be  secured. 

15  The  Carpenter,  September,  1906,  p.  40. 

Bricklayer  and  Mason,  May,  1908,  p.  70. 

Proceedings,  1912,  p.  21. 
}8  Proceedings,  1906,  p.  193. 
89  Sheet  Metal  Workers'  Journal,  October,  1915,  p.  399. 


UNION  AGENCIES  FOR  DISTRIBUTION  OF  WORKMEN         89 

In  those  unions  which  do  not  maintain  employment  bu- 
reaus at  the  national  headquarters,  additional  workmen  are 
generally  secured  by  one  local  union's  writing  or  telegraph- 
ing to  other  local  unions.  This  method  is  largely  employed 
by  the  building-trades  unions.  When  New  York  City  is  in 
need  of  additional  building-trades  mechanics,  either  Phila- 
delphia, Baltimore,  Boston,  Albany,  or  Pittsburg  is  notified 
of  the  shortage  of  men.  Sometimes,  as  is  the  case  with  the 
Elevator  Constructors  and  Bridge  and  Structural  Iron 
Workers,  the  business  agent  telegraphs  to  the  local  union 
of  a  nearby  city  to  send  a  certain  number  of  men,  with  the 
understanding  that  these  men  will  be  guaranteed  employ- 
ment if  they  come.  The  following  letter,  which  was  printed 
in  the  Bridge  and  Structural  Iron  Workers'  Journal,  was 
written  by  the  business  agent  of  Salt  Lake  City,  and  illus- 
trates the  methods  in  force.  "  I  received  a  telegram  from  busi- 
ness agent  Hendricks  of  Los  Angeles  asking  me  if  I  could 
furnish  eight  men  for  the  San  Pedro  at  Calientes,  Nevada.  I 
replied  that  I  could  send  as  many  men  as  was  needed.  I 
received  another  telegram  to  send  eleven  men,  so  I  sent 
them  out  on  the  24th  on  the  bases  of  $4.50  for  nine  hours 
and  transportation  expenses."40 

But  the  greater  part  of  the  movement  of  trade  unionists 
in  search  of  employment  does  not  result  either  from  the 
activities  of  the  union  employment  bureaus  or  through  the 
notification  of  one  local  union  by  another  that  men  are 
needed.  The  ordinary  member  realizes  that  local  unions 
do  not  generally  send  for  additional  men  until  the  pressure 
from  employers  forces  them  to  do  so.  He  knows  that  there 
are  numerous  instances  in  which  other  local  unions  are  not 
notified  of  opportunities  for  employment  even  after  the  em- 
ployers register  their  wants.  Therefore,  workmen  keep  in 
communication  with  one  another  and  when  the  prospects 
are  good,  those  who  are  cognizant  of  the  fact  notify  their 
friends.  Many  workmen  also  write  to  the  various  business 
agents  and  local  union  secretaries  to  inquire  about  the  pros- 

40  The  Bridgemen's  Magazine,  July,  1911,  p.  448. 


9O         UNEMPLOYMENT   AND  AMERICAN   TRADE   UNIONS 

pects  for  employment.  This  is  the  manner  in  which  the 
unemployed,  who  are  not  habitual  "travelers,"  generally 
secure  their  information.  At  times  the  local  union  secre- 
taries complain  that  they  are  compelled  to  answer  too  many 
letters.  The  Washington  business  agent  of  the  Bridge  and 
Structural  Iron  Workers  reported  in  1904  that  he  received 
an  average  of  four  letters  each  day  from  members  asking 
for  information  concerning  the  prospects  for  employment.41 
Other  workmen  write  to  their  friends  in  other  cities  inquir- 
ing as  to  the  conditions  of  trade. 

We  have  outlined,  so  far  as  ascertainable,  the  methods  of 
those  unions  which  have  attempted  to  devise  means  for 
giving  information  to  the  unemployed  which  will  enable 
them  to  find  employment  in  other  places.  There  are  in  the 
United  States  over  125  national  unions.  Of  these,  we  have 
found  that  only  14  maintain  employment  bureaus.  And  of 
these  14  bureaus,  only  seven  can  be  said  to  possess  merit. 
The  value  of  the  others  to  the  unemployed  is  negligible. 
Numerous  reasons  have  been  advanced  by  trade  unionists 
for  the  lack  of  success  of  the  employment  bureaus  which 
have  been  established,  and  for  the  fact  that  the  other  unions 
do  not  even  attempt  to  provide  means  for  the  dissemination 
of  a  knowledge  of  trade  conditions.  The  failure  of  Ameri- 
can unions  to  solve  the  problem  of  transferring  their  mem- 
bers from  localities  in  which  trade  is  poor  to  those  in  which 
work  can  be  secured  is  chiefly  attributable  to  the  selfishness 
of  the  local  unions  There  are  very  few  trades  in  which 
traveling  members  do  not  receive  a  cool  welcome  from  the 
local  unions  in  which  they  deposit  their  cards.  The  mem- 
bers of  a  local  union  look  upon  the  work  to  be  done  in  their 
community  as  belonging  to  them,  and  they  resent  any  in- 
trusion upon  the  part  of  non-residents.  Although  this  at- 
titude is  contrary  to  the  doctrines  of  unionism,  the  greater 
number  of  union  officials  concede  its  existence.  It  is  this 
spirit  which  has  made  it  impossible  to  induce  the  local  unions 
of  the  Bricklayers  and  Masons,  the  Cigar  Makers  and  vari- 

41  Ibid.,  August,  1904,  p.  28. 


UNION  AGENCIES  FOR  DISTRIBUTION  OF  WORKMEN         91 

ous  other  unions,  to  report  to  other  localities  when  men  were 
needed. 

Even  when  additional  men  are  in  great  demand  the  local 
union  will  not  attempt  to  obtain  members  from  other  locali- 
ties. The  secretary  of  the  Bricklayers  and  Masons  in  1901 
said:  "The  local  unions  would  rather  allow  non-union  men 
to  be  employed  at  periods  of  prosperity  than  secure  outside 
union  men,  for  fear  that  the  latter  would  stay  in  town  after 
the  busy  season  was  over,  and  thus  there  would  be  less 
work  per  capita  for  the  members."42  Many  devices  besides 
the  use  of  non-union  workmen  are  practised  in  order  to 
minimize  the  demand  for  workmen  from  other  cities.  Over- 
time is  frequently  worked  and  it  has  been  said  that  the  men 
will  perform  work  which  would  ordinarily  require  the  serv- 
ices of  more  men.  The  editor  of  the  Bookbinders'  Journal, 
in  remarking  upon  the  selfishness  of  the  local  unions,  said : 
"  I  am  confident  that  the  spirit  of  home-guardism  has  been 
and  still  is  detrimental  to  our  interests,  and  best  shows  a 
clannish  spirit  which  often  keeps  an  extra  man  out  of  a 
shop  while  a  crew  of  five  men  will  go  on  and  do  the  work 
of  a  crew  formerly  consisting  of  six  men."43 

The  local  unions  have  not  been  content  with  denying  to 
non-residents  the  knowledge  of  trade  conditions,  but  have 
also  enforced  rules  which  are  designed  to  make  it  more 
difficult  for  the  traveling  members  to  gain  admission  to  the 
local  union.  Many  of  the  local  unions  of  the  Bricklayers 
demand  the  sum  of  $5.00  before  traveling  cards  are  ac- 
cepted.** 

Some  local  unions  have  gone  even  further,  according  to 
the  secretary  of  the  Electrical  Workers,  who  says  that  in 
1915  complaints  were  received  that  the  local  unions  in  some 
localities  had  refused  to  accept  traveling  cards  on  any  con- 
dition.45 Secretary  Skemp  of  the  Painters  reported  to  the 
convention  of  1915  that  there  was  a  "growing  disposition  to 

**The  Bricklayer  and  Mason,  September,  1901,  p.  I. 

"International  Bookbinder,  June,  1911,  p.  238. 

**  The  Thirty-fifth  Annual  Report  of  the  President  and  Secretary, 

IQOO,  p.  128. 

45  Electrical  Worker,  August,  1914,  p.  370. 


92         UNEMPLOYMENT  AND   AMERICAN   TRADE  UNIONS 

deny  traveling  members  the  right  to  deposit  clearance  cards," 
and  that  "all  kinds  of  schemes  are  devised  and  excuses 
invented  to  keep  the  stranger  without  the  gate  and  reserve 
the  work  for  the  resident  member.46 

Even  after  the  traveling  member  has  gained  admission, 
he  is  not  infrequently  discriminated  against.  The  local 
unions,  in  many  cases,  manage  so  that  resident  members 
shall  be  given  preference  over  traveling  members  when  em- 
ployment is  offered.  It  is  a  well  known  fact  that  in  the 
building-trades  unions  of  New  York,  Chicago  and  several 
other  cities  the  non-resident  member  has  small  chance  of 
securing  work  until  the  business  agent  has  placed  the  resi- 
dent members.  A  national  rule  of  the  Cutters  in  the  Flint 
Glass  Workers  gives  preference  to  local  workmen,47  and 
there  have  been  cases  in  the  Marble  Workers48  and  in  other 
unions  where  traveling  members  who  had  deposited  their 
cards  and  had  received  employment  were  forced  by  the 
business  agent  to  transfer  to  another  city  in  order  to  "  make 
room  for  resident  members  who  were  unemployed." 

The  exclusiveness  of  the  local  union  is  not  always  due  to 
the  desire  to  retain  all  work  for  the  resident  members.  Fre- 
quently a  local  union  desires  to  make  demands  upon  the  em- 
ployers for  an  increase  of  wages  or  for  better  working  condi- 
tions, and  a  time  when  the  locality  is  in  need  of  additional 
men  offers  a  favorable  occasion  for  the  local  union  to  en- 
force its  demands.  At  such  a  time  the  local  union  does  not 
want  the  information  that  employment  conditions  are  good 
to  reach  other  localities,  and  consequently  it  will  try  to  keep 
the  traveler  from  the  city. 

If  the  trade  unionist  has  secured,  through  the  aid  of  the 
agencies  described  above,  or  otherwise,  information  as  to 
where  he  will  be  able  to  secure  employment,  there  remains 
the  problem  of  getting  to  the  place  where  employment  may 

48  Report  of  General  Officers  to  the  Eleventh  Convention,  19:3, 
p.  71. 

47  Rules  of  the  Cutters,  No.  22,  in  Proceedings  of  the  Flint  Glass 
Workers,  1911,  p.  143. 

48  Proceedings,  1913,  p.  163. 


UNION  AGENCIES  FOR  DISTRIBUTION  OF  WORKMEN         93 

be  had.  The  knowledge  that  a  position  can  be  secured  in 
another  city  is  of  no  value  to  a  workman  unless  he  is  able 
to  make  the  transfer.  Inasmuch  as  the  distances  to  be 
traversed  in  some  cases  require  the  expenditure  of  a  con- 
siderable sum  of  money,  the  workman  sometimes  finds  him- 
self unable  to  go. 

In  some  trades  the  employers  advance  traveling  expenses, 
but  this  is  not  usual.  Only  in  periods  of  great  prosperity 
are  such  instances  general.  Thus  in  1901,  during  a  scarcity 
of  granite  cutters  in  the  East,  a  firm  in  Hall  Quarry,  Maine, 
furnished  transportation  expenses  to  twenty  men  from  Ray- 
mond, California.49  But  in  a  normal  season  employers  of 
granite  cutters  do  not  advance  expenses  to  their  workmen. 
In  some  unions,  such  as  the  Elevator  Constructors  and 
Bridge  and  Structural  Iron  Workers  whose  members  are 
taken  by  the  employers  from  one  city  to  another,  the  ex- 
penses are  paid  by  the  employers.  As  a  general  rule,  how- 
ever, the  workmen  are  forced  to  rely  upon  their  union  or 
their  own  resources  for  traveling  expenses  even  when  they 
are  engaged  by  an  employer  in  another  locality. 

Only  in  a  small  percentage  of  cases  are  workmen  assured 
of  employment  before  the  actual  transfer  is  made.  They 
may  have  been  led  to  expect  work  at  such  and  such  a  place, 
but  it  is  usually  only  after  their  arrival  that  they  obtain  em- 
ployment. In  these  cases  the  workman  can  not  look  to  the 
employer  for  transportation  expenses.  If  he  is  unable  to 
pay  the  expense,  his  recourse  must  in  most  cases  be  to  his 
union.60  Many  of  the  unions  have  considered  it  their  duty 
to  furnish  members  who  desire  to  travel  with  the  necessary 
transportation  expenses,  either  as  a  loan  or  a  gift. 

The  following  table  shows  the  amounts  which  have  been 
expended  for  this  benefit  since  1903  by  those  unions  which 
report  to  the  American  Federation  of  Labor. 

49  Granite  Cutters'  Journal,  August,  1901,  p.  5. 

50  Some  of  the  railroad  systems  have  agreed  to  give  transporta- 
tion to  members  of  the  Brotherhoods  who  are  unemployed  and  are 
traveling  in  search  of  work,  provided  they  have  been  engaged  by  a 
common  carrier  within  the  previous  ninety  days.    This  is  done  under 
a  provision  made  by  the  Interstate  Commerce  Commission  (Loco- 
motive Engineers'  Journal,  January,  1915,  p.  44). 


94 


UNEMPLOYMENT   AND   AMERICAN    TRADE   UNIONS 


AMOUNTS  PAID  AS  TRAVELING  LOANS  AND  BENEFITS 


Year 

Amount 

Year 

Amount 

1903 
1904 

1905 
1906 
1907 
1908 

$84,891.58 
73,441.90 
62,989.71 

57.340.93 
53,598.86 
51,093.86 

I9IO 
I9II 
1912 

1913 
I9H 

1915 

$42,999-55 
58,784-71 
40,571.02 
33,693.10 
54,404.90 
70,346.70 

1909 

51,967.87 

Total  

$746,122.69 

The  systems  of  traveling  loans  and  benefits  in  American 
trade  unions  have  been,  generally  speaking,  failures.  At  one 
time  or  another  the  following  unions  have  paid  traveling 
loans  or  benefits:  Cigar  Makers,  Flint  Glass  Workers, 
Granite  Cutters,  Leather  Workers  on  Horse  Goods,  Lithog- 
raphers, Machinists,  Typographia,  and  White  Rats  Actors. 
Only  the  Cigar  Makers  and  Lithographers  have  maintained 
their  systems  to  the  present. 

During  the  earliest  years  of  the  Cigar  Makers'  Union 
members  who  desired  to  travel  in  search  of  employment 
were  granted  loans  by  the  local  unions.  As  no  great  efforts 
were  made  by  the  local  unions  to  which  the  members  trans- 
ferred to  collect  these  loans,  the  system  of  loans  from  local 
unions  was  superseded  in  1867  by  a  system  established  and 
maintained  by  the  national  union.51  Under  this  plan  an  un- 
employed member  was  entitled  to  a  loan  sufficient  to  take 
him  to  the  nearest  union.  The  loan  was  to  be  repaid  to  the 
local  union  in  which  the  member  secured  employment  in 
weekly  installments  to  the  amount  of  twenty  per  cent  of  the 
member's  earnings.52  The  carelessness  of  the  secretaries 
in  collecting  these  loans  made  the  system  an  absolute  failure 
and  it  was  abolished  in  i878.53 

The  local  union  of  Warren,  Pennsylvania,  then  proposed 
that  the  National  Union  maintain  a  "  traveling  fund  "  for 
the  purpose  of  aiding  traveling  members.  This  aid  was  to 
be  a  gift  and  not  a  loan,  but  the  measure  failed  of  adoption. 

51  Proceedings,  1867,  p.  155. 

52  Constitution,  1867,  art.  II. 

58  Cigar  Makers'  Journal,  October  5,  1878,  p.  3. 


UNION  AGENCIES  FOR  DISTRIBUTION  OF  WORKMEN         95 

However,  in  the  following  year  Secretary  Samuel  Gompers 
of  the  New  York  local  union  proposed  a  new  plan  which 
was  adopted  by  referendum  vote.64  It  provided  that  any 
member  in  good  standing  for  six  months  who  was  unem- 
ployed and  desired  to  travel  was  entitled  to  a  loan  sufficient 
for  tranportation  expenses  by  the  cheapest  route  to  the 
nearest  local  union,  and  so  on  to  the  next  union,  until  the 
loans  reached  the  sum  of  $2O.oo.55  The  amount  of  any  one 
loan  was  limited  to  $12.00  in  i8&4,56  and  in  1896  it  was 
further  reduced  to  $8.oo.57  The  system  in  operation  at 
present  provides  that  members  who  desire  to  obtain  traveling 
loans  must  have  been  in  good  standing  for  one  year.  After 
obtaining  employment  the  borrower  must  pay  to  the  col- 
lector of  the  shop  in  which  he  is  employed  ten  per  cent  of 
his  weekly  earnings  until  the  loan  is  repaid.58 

The  Granite  Cutters  established  a  traveling  loan  system  in 
1880,  three  years  after  the  organization  of  the  national 
union.  It  provided  that  any  member  in  good  standing  for 
at  least  six  months  who  was  not  able  to  obtain  employ- 
ment and  wished  to  transfer  to  another  local  union  was 
entitled  to  a  loan  of  not  more  than  $10.00.  It  was  neces- 
sary for  the  borrower  to  secure  two  members  in  good  stand- 
ing to  become  security  for  him,  and  the  loan  was  to  be 
repaid  in  installments  of  ten  per  cent  of  the  weekly  earn- 
ings.59 In  1888  the  latter  provision  was  changed  so  that 
the  member  was  required  to  pay  the  loan  in  installments  of 
twenty-five  per  cent  of  his  weekly  earnings.60  From  the 
outset  the  system  was  a  failure  on  account  of  the  difficulty 
in  securing  payment  of  loans.  It  was  thought  that  the  pro- 
vision that  those  acting  as  security  for  the  loans  should  be 
held  responsible  would  prove  a  safeguard.  But  in  1891  the 
secretary  said  that  the  majority  of  the  members  "regarded 

54  Ibid.,  August,  1879,  p.  2. 

55  Constitution,  1880,  art.  4. 

56  Constitution,  1884,  art.  7. 

57  Constitution,  1896,  art.  27. 

68  Constitution,  1912,  sees.  104-116. 

59  Constitution,  1880,  art.  43. 

60  Constitution,  1888,  art.  33. 


96         UNEMPLOYMENT   AND   AMERICAN    TRADE   UNIONS 

vouching  as  an  empty  formality "  as  was  shown  by  the 
number  of  loans  then  unpaid.61  President  Duncan  states 
that  the  abuses  finally  became  so  flagrant  that  the  entire 
system  was  abolished  in  1897.  There  were  instances  in 
which  three  members  would  unite  for  the  purpose  of  secur- 
ing loans.  Each  would  secure  a  loan  with  the  other  two 
as  security,  and  in  many  cases  none  of  the  money  was  re- 
paid.62 In  March,  1902,  five  years  after  the  abolition  of 
the  system,  the  secretary  published  a  list  of  loans  amounting 
to  several  thousand  dollars  which  were  still  unpaid.63 

The  history  of  the  traveling  loan  in  the  Flint  Glass  Work- 
ers is  much  the  same.  During  the  earliest  years  of  the 
union  the  unemployed  who  desired  to  travel  in  search  of 
employment  were  furnished  transportation  by  the  national 
union.  The  applicant  was  required  before  a  loan  was 
granted  to  submit  satisfactory  evidence  that  he  had  secured 
a  position.  The  system  proved  a  complete  failure.  Secre- 
tary Kunzler  reported  to  the  convention  of  1896  that  some 
members  had  procured  loans  by  means  of  false  telegrams 
and  letters  which  purported  to  show  that  there  were  jobs 
at  some  place  ready  for  them.  He  also  said  that  of  the 
$10,000  which  had  been  loaned  from  1885  to  J896  only 
eighteen  per  cent  had  been  repaid.64 

At  various  conventions  -the  union  adopted  rules  which  it 
was  thought  would  safeguard  the  union  against  unauthor- 
ized loans,  but  the  traveling  members  always  succeeded  in 
evading  them.  During  the  years  preceding  1902  the  system 
was  still  further  abused  and  the  loans  became  in  reality  gifts. 
Secretary  Dobbins  reported  to  the  convention  of  1902  that 
of  the  $3,376.04  loaned  during1  the  previous  year  only 
$975-53  had  been  repaid,  and  a  large  part  of  the  sum  re- 
ceived was  deducted  from  strike  benefits  and  bills  sent  to 
the  office  for  personal  services.  He  said  that  members  still 
persisted  in  sending  to  the  union  letters  and  telegrams 

61  Granite  Cutters'  Journal,  April,  1891,  p.  4. 
82  Letter  to  the  writer,  October  20,  1915. 
63  Granite  Cutters'  Journal,  March,  1902,  p.  14. 
04  Proceedings,  1896,  p.  87. 


UNION  AGENCIES  FOR  DISTRIBUTION  OF  WORKMEN         97 

written  by  one  member  to  another  telling  him  to  come  on 
immediately  as  there  was  a  job  awaiting  him,  but  in  the 
majority  of  cases  the  member  never  transferred  to  another 
city.65  At  this  convention  the  membership  became  so 
aroused  over  the  granting  of  illegal  loans  that  there  was  a 
movement  to  abolish  the  whole  system,  but  it  did  not  suc- 
ceed.66 

At  the  convention  in  1904  several  new  provisions  were 
adopted.  The  national  secretary  was  to  loan  no  money  to 
members  except  for  transportation  expenses  and  then  only 
when  the  applicant  had  a  letter  or  telegram  from  an  em- 
ployer or  local  union  to  prove  that  the  member  was  guar- 
anteed a  job.  The  member  securing  the  loan  was  required 
to  sign  a  promissory  note  for  the  amount  borrowed  and  was 
to  pay  ten  per  cent  of  his  earnings  until  the  loan  was  repaid. 
The  national  secretary  was  to  notify  the  trade  by  circular 
of  the  loans  granted  and  the  local  unions  were  held  respon- 
sible for  the  debts  of  their  members.67  As  a  result  of  these 
rules  a  greater  percentage  of  the  loans  were  repaid,  and 
there  was  a  great  increase  in  the  amounts  loaned.  The  union 
was  still  unable  to  force  many  local  unions  to  collect  the 
loans  and  in  several  instances  local  unions  were  not  per- 
mitted to  send  delegates  to  the  convention  because  they 
were  not  prompt  in  the  collection  of  loans.  Frequently, 
delegates  to  the  conventions  were  found  to  be  the  worst 
offenders.  In  April,  1907,  the  national  secretary  issued  a 
pamphlet  containing  the  names  of  1304  members  who  had 
borrowed  an  aggregate  sum  of  $24,000,  an  average  of  more 
than  $18.  Several  months  later,  the  secretary  reported  that 
he  had  succeeded  in  finding  only  109  of  the  debtors.  When 
this  was  reported  to  the  convention  there  was  little  opposi- 
tion to  the  abolition  of  the  entire  system  of  traveling  loans.68 

During  the  next  few  years  the  traveling  members  waged 
a  campaign  for  the  reestablishment  of  the  loan  system  and 

66  Proceedings,  1902,  pp.  127,  128. 
1  Ibid.,  p.  203. 

Proceedings,  1904,  pp.  229,  230. 

68  Proceedings,  1907,  pp.  93,  174. 

7 


98         UNEMPLOYMENT   AND   AMERICAN    TRADE   UNIONS 

this,  coupled  with  the  scarcity  of  men  in  some  places,  led  to 
a  reconsideration  at  the  convention  in  1910.  It  was  said 
that  the  abolition  of  the  system  had  "worked  a  hardship 
upon  our  members  in  not  being  able  to  secure  transporta- 
tion from  one  locality  to  another  and  that  it  has  caused 
many  complaints  from  manufacturers  on  account  of  many 
places  standing  idle  in  their  factories."  The  convention 
reestablished  the  system  with  entitely  new  rules.89  It  was 
provided  that  a  member  should  have  been  unemployed  for 
two  weeks  and  must  be  free  of  any  indebtedness  to  the  union 
before  he  was  entitled  to  a  loan.  He  was  required  also  to 
show  a  letter  from  the  employer  or  local  union  to  prove  that 
he  was  guaranteed  a  position.  After  securing  employment 
ten  per  cent  of  his  earnings  were  to  be  paid  until  the  loan 
was  repaid.  A  local  union  which  accepted  the  card  of  a 
member  who  had  borrowed  transportation  expenses  and 
failed  to  collect  ten  per  cent  of  his  earnings  was  held  re- 
sponsible for  the  debt.70 

During  the  first  year  of  operation  only  thirty-five  per  cent 
of  the  loans  were  repaid  and  the  abuses  which  characterized 
the  old  system  soon  reappeared.71  The  national  officers 
were  powerless  to  prevent  the  granting  of  illegal  loans  and 
were  unable  to  force  the  local-union  secretaries  to  collect 
the  loans  when  made.  The  abuses  became  so  flagrant  that 
the  system  was  again  abolished  at  the  convention  in  I9I3,72 
and  no  loans  have  been  granted  since  January  i,  1914. 
However,  at  the  convention  in  1915  there  was  a  movement 
for  its  reestablishment,  but  owing  to  the  strong  opposition 
of  the  officers  the  motion  failed  of  adoption.73 

The  White  Rats  Actors  established  in  1912  a  system  of 
traveling  loans  which  was  not  unlike  that  of  the  Flint  Glass 
Workers.  Only  those  members  who  could  show  an  "  en- 
forceable contract  with  a  responsible  manager  for  an  en- 
gagement" were  entitled  to  a  loan.  The  borrower  gave  a 

69  Proceedings,  1910,  p.  143. 

70  Ibid.,  p.  153. 

71  Proceedings,  1912,  p.  216. 

72  Proceedings,  1913,  p.  292. 

73  Proceedings,  1915,  p.  315. 


UNION  AGENCIES  FOR  DISTRIBUTION  OF  WORKMEN         99 

promissory  note  for  the  amount  loaned  and  agreed  to  repay 
the  same  out  of  the  first  week's  salary.  If  he  failed  to  re- 
pay the  loan,  the  union  attached  his  wages.74  With  such 
precautionary  measures  it  was  thought  that  very  few  losses 
would  result.  During  1912  there  was  loaned  $32,000,  of 
which  $14,155  was  outstanding  in  April,  I9I3-75  During 
the  next  two  years  about  $60,000  was  loaned  and  the  amount 
which  was  not  repaid  of  the  loans  granted  during  the 
three  years  of  the  operation  of  the  system  was  $14,000. 
Thus  the  union  lost  fifteen  per  cent  of  the  amount  loaned. 
The  members  decided  that  the  system  was  costing  too  much 
in  proportion  to  the  benefits  received  and  abolished  it  in 
August,  191 5.™ 

The  Leather  Workers  on  Horse  Goods  established  a  trav- 
eling loan  system  when  the  union  was  organized  in  1896. 
It  was  provided  that  an  unemployed  member  could  obtain 
from  a  local  union  a  loan  sufficient  to  transport  him  to  the 
nearest  branch  in  the  direction  he  wished  to  travel.  The 
first  loan  was  not  to  exceed  $12.50  while  the  total  amount 
which  could  be  borrowed  in  any  year  was  $21.00.  The  loan 
was  to  be  repaid  in  installments  of  fifteen  per  cent  of  the 
member's  weekly  earnings.77  Flagrant  abuses  soon  crept  in 
and  the  president  frequently  notified  the  local  union  secre- 
taries that  many  illegal  loans  were  being  granted  and  only 
a  small  percentage  of  loans  were  being  repaid.  But  no 
improvement  resulted  from  the  publicity  given  to  the  abuses, 
and  the  system  was  abolished  in  October,  I9O4.78 

The  Machinists,  soon  after  the  union  was  organized,  also 
established  a  traveling  loan  system.  The  loans  were  granted 
by  the  local  unions  and  it  appears  that  they  suffered  all 
losses.  It  had  been  expected  that  the  local  unions  would 
be  careful  in  granting  loans  and  in  seeing  that  they  were 
repaid.  In  1895  the  president  reported  that  during  the  two 

74  Constitution,  1912,  art.  14,  sec.  i. 

75  Letter  from  Secretary  W.  W.  Waters  to  the  writer,  April  22, 
I9I3- 

1  Letter  from  Secretary  to  the  writer,  November  8,  1915. 

77  Constitution,  1896,  art.  4,  sec.  I. 

78  Leather  Workers'  Journal,  January,  1905,  p.  252. 


previous  years  $5,000  had  been  loaned,  and  the  system  had 
"been  unmercifully  abused."79  During  the  next  two  years 
$6,124  was  loaned  to  traveling  members.  Only  a  small 
amount  was  ever  repaid.  This  was  due,  the  president  said, 
to  the  fact  that  there  was  no  provision  as  to  the  limit  of  time 
for  the  payment  of  the  loans.80  At  the  convention  in  1897 
it  was  provided  that  the  loans  must  be  repaid  within  ten 
weeks  after  they  were  granted.81  The  unemployed  mem- 
ber was  not  granted  a  loan  unless  his  dues  had  been  paid 
to  date,  and  the  amount  that  could  be  borrowed  at  any  one 
time  was  not  to  exceed  $5.00,  nor  could  any  further  loan  be 
secured  until  the  previous  one  had  been  repaid.  The  finan- 
cial secretary  of  the  local  union  to  which  the  member  trav- 
eled was  required  to  collect  the  sum  borrowed  and  forward 
it  to  the  local  union  which  granted  it.  The  system  failed 
completely.  In  1903  President  O'Connell  said  that  only  a 
small  percentage  of  the  loans  were  repaid,  that  the  system 
had  tended  to  encourage  dishonesty,  and  that  it  had  caused 
an  unlimited  number  of  disputes  among  the  local  unions. 
For  these  reasons  he  recommended  that  it  be  abolished.82 
The  convention  in  1903  decided  that  no  further  loans  would 
be  granted  after  July  31  of  that  year.83 

The  system  of  traveling  loans  of  the  Lithographers  is 
similar  to  that  of  the  Machinists  in  that  the  loans  are  made 
by  the  local  unions  and  all  losses  are  met  by  the  local  unions. 
The  national  constitution  provides  that  any  member  who 
desires  to  travel  in  search  of  employment,  and  is  in  need 
of  financial  assistance  shall  make  application  to  the  local 
union  for  a  loan.  The  local  executive  board  investigates 
the  application  and  grants  the  loan  if  the  member  appears 
worthy.  The  amount  of  the  loan  is  entered  in  the  member's 
dues-book  and  it  is  the  duty  of  the  secretary  of  the  local 
union  to  which  the  member  transfers,  to  collect  the  loan  and 

79  Proceedings,  1895,  p.  12. 

80  Proceedings,  1897,  p.  8. 

81  Constitution,  1897,  art.  10,  sec.  3. 

82  Proceedings,  1903,  p.  402. 

83  Ibid.,  p.  531. 


UNION  AGENCIES  FOR  DISTRIBUTION  OF  WORKMEN       IOI 

return  it  to  the  local  union  which  granted  it.84  No  statistics 
are  available  as  to  the  amounts  which  have  been  loaned  and 
collected  during  the  existence  of  the  system,  but  it  is  said 
that  the  members  make  considerable  use  of  it. 

The  Deutsch-Amerikanischen  Typographia  established  its 
traveling  benefit  in  connection  with  an  out-of-work  benefit 
in  i884.85  This  system  differed  from  others  in  that  the 
traveling  member  was  given  the  transportation  expenses  as 
a  gift  and  not  as  a  loan.  An  unemployed  member  in  good 
standing  for  six  months  was  entitled  to  two  cents  per  mile 
for  the  first  two  hundred  miles  and  one  cent  for  each  addi- 
tional mile  he  wished  to  travel,  provided  that  the  total  sum 
did  not  exceed  $10.  After  spending  three  months  in  the 
local  union  to  which  he  traveled  he  was  entitled  to  trans- 
portation expenses  to  another  local  union,  but  he  could  not 
draw  more  than  $25  in  one  year.  If  a  member  became  un- 
employed through  his  own  fault,  he  was  not  entitled  to  the 
benefit  for  three  months,  and  if  the  position  had  been  given 
up  voluntarily,  he  could  not  receive  the  benefit  unless  the 
executive  council  of  the  local  union  approved  his  action. 
Those  who  drew  the  traveling  benefit  were  supposed  to 
transfer  at  once  to  another  city  or  return  the  amount  re- 
ceived. Although  the  benefit  was  free,  it  appears  never  to 
have  been  greatly  utilized.  For  example,  in  1907  there  were 
only  fifteen  members  who  applied  for  benefits  totaling 
$104.60.  The  system  was  abolished  in  1908.  Secretary 
Miller  explains  that  this  was  on  account  of  the  flagrant 
abuses  of  the  benefit  by  the  members.  He  says  that  mem- 
bers living  in  Chicago  and  the  Middle  West  when  going  on 
a  vacation  trip  to  the  East  or  to  Europe  would  draw  the 
maximum  benefit.  In  short,  he  says,  the  benefit  was  used 
as  a  means  of  partly  defraying  the  expenses  of  members  on 
"holiday  trips."86 

At  the  Painters'  convention  in  1910  there  was  a  move- 

84  Constitution,  1913,  art.  20,  sec.  i. 

89  Letter  from  Secretary  Hugo  Miller  to  the  writer,  October  19, 

15. 

«•  Ibid. 


IO2        UNEMPLOYMENT   AND   AMERICAN   TRADE   UNIONS 

ment  to  provide  traveling  members  with  a  loan  of  not  more 
than  $10,  but  the  proposed  plan  received  little  attention.87 
The  Bricklayers  and  Masons  in  i87388  and  the  Plumbers  in 
iQoS89  also  considered  the  advisability  of  establishing  a 
traveling  loan  system,  but  both  proposals  failed  of  adoption. 
At  the  Typographical  convention  in  1889  there  was  proposed 
a  traveling  loan  of  two  cents  per  mile,  but  it  was  defeated.90 

In  those  unions  which  have  not  established  a  national  trav- 
eling loan  system,  some  of  the  local  unions  maintain  funds 
from  which  the  members  who  desire  to  travel  may  secure  a 
loan,  or  from  which  the  "traveler"  may  secure  a  gift  of  a  few 
dollars  to  aid  him  in  transferring  to  another  city.  If  a  mem- 
ber is  assured  of  a  job  or  has  fair  prospects  of  securing 
employment  in  another  city,  there  is  scarcely  a  local  union 
in  any  trade  which  will  not  advance  him  the  necessary  trav- 
eling expenses.  But  if  the  member  applying  for  a  loan  is 
a  "traveler,"  or  has  little  prospect  of  securing  employment 
in  another  city,  the  local  unions  do  not  always  grant  the 
loan.  Generally  the  amounts  of  the  loans  are  entered  in  the 
members'  dues-books  and  the  local  unions  in  which  the 
card  is  deposited  are  supposed  to  collect  the  loans  and  return 
them  to  the  local  unions  which  granted  them. 

The  systems  of  traveling  loans  and  benefits  have  failed 
largely  because  they  have  induced  needless  traveling  through 
the  administrative  inefficiency  of  the  local-union  secretaries. 
During  the  first  year's  operation  of  the  Cigar  Makers'  sys- 
tem, the  condition  of  trade  was  bad  all  over  the  country. 
The  members  were  told  that  there  were  no  jobs  to  be  had 
in  any  city,91  but  since  the  traveler  could  secure  a  loan  from 
the  union  many  went  in  search  of  work.  A  traveling  loan 
system  is  socially  injurious  when  a  workman  can  secure  a 
loan  despite  the  fact  that  there  is  no  work  for  him  to  do  in 
the  locality  to  which  he  transfers.  The  union  works  a  hard- 
ship upon  its  members  when  it  grants  loans  without  first 

87  Proceedings,  1910,  p.  44. 

88  Proceedings,  1873,  p.  27. 

89  Proceedings,  1008,  p.  91. 

90  Proceedings,  1889,  p.  124., 

91  Cigar  Makers'  Journal,  July  10,  1881,  p.  i. 


UNION  AGENCIES  FOR  DISTRIBUTION  OF  WORKMEN      103 

directing  members  to  places  where  employment  may  be  had. 
For  many  years  the  English  trade  unions  granted  traveling 
benefits  in  the  same  manner  as  do  the  American  unions,  that 
is,  without  ascertaining  whether  the  member  was  going  to 
improve  his  condition  by  transferring.  Within  recent  years, 
however,  the  English  system  has  undergone  a  considerable 
change,  and  traveling  loans  and  benefits  are  now  granted 
chiefly  to  those  for  whom  employment  has  been  found  in 
another  city.  Since  traveling  loans  are  now  granted  in  the 
United  States  chiefly  by  the  local  unions,  which  usually 
demand  that  the  applicant  shall  be  assured  of  employment 
before  the  loan  is  granted,  it  is  probably  true  that  the  trav- 
eling loan  is  now  somewhat  more  useful  than  before. 

Another  cause  of  the  failure  of  the  traveling  loan  systems 
was  the  granting  of  unauthorized  loans.  Although  the 
unions  had  generally  provided  apparently  stringent  rules 
for  the  administration  of  the  system,  many  unauthorized 
loans  were  granted.  Among  the  Cigar  Makers  this  abuse 
appeared  at  an  early  date.  In  1881  the  secretary  remarked 
that  he  knew  of  many  members  who  had  drawn  loans  and 
never  left  their  homes,  and  of  others  who  claimed  money 
for  a  distance  of  two  hundred  miles  and  did  not  go  farther 
than  fifty  miles.92  The  local  union  secretaries  became  so 
careless  in  the  matter  of  granting  loans  that  the  union  made 
a  rule  that  secretaries  who  granted  unauthorized  loans  were 
to  be  fined  $5.  In  June,  1884,  twenty-one  secretaries  were 
fined.91  The  loan  systems  of  the  German  Printers,  Granite 
Cutters,  Flint  Glass  Workers,  Leather  Workers  on  Horse 
Goods,  Machinists,  and  White  Rats  Actors  were  abolished 
primarily  on  account  of  the  abuses  in  granting  loans.  It 
seems  that  the  local-union  secretaries  granted  loans  in  prac- 
tically all  cases,  simply  trusting  that,  as  the  loan  was  entered 
in  the  members'  dues-books,  the  local  unions  to  which  they 
traveled  would  collect  the  money. 

Through  the  carelessness  of  the  secretaries  in  the  admin- 
istration of  the  systems  the  amounts  of  loans  which  were 

92  Ibid.,  p.  i. 

98  Ibid.,  July,  1884,  p.  3. 


IO4      UNEMPLOYMENT   AND   AMERICAN    TRADE   UNIONS 

not  repaid  were  very  large  in  some  cases.  During  the 
thirty-five  years  existence  of  the  Cigar  Makers'  system, 
there  has  been  expended  $1,337,271,  or  an  average  of 
$38,207  each  year.  The  amount  loaned  per  capita  has 
varied  from  63  cents  in  1880  to  $3.48  in  1884,  and  has  aver- 
aged during  the  period  $1.50.  On  the  first  of  January, 
1915,  there  were  outstanding  loans  to  the  amount  of  $109,- 
220.31.  President  Perkins  states  that  of  this  sum  about 
one-half  is  collectible.94  Thus  the  cost  of  the  system  for 
thirty-five  years  has  been  about  $55,000,  an  average  annual 
per  capita  of  8  cents.  The  Flint  Glass  Workers  have  not 
expended  nearly  so  much  on  their  system  as  the  Cigar 
Makers.  During  the  ten  years  in  which  loans  were  granted, 
the  sum  of  $37,821  was  expended,  an  average  of  $3,782. 
The  amount  loaned  per  capita  varied  from  10  cents  in  1914 
to  73  cents  in  1907,  and  the  average  annual  per  capita  ex- 
penditure was  50  cents.  When  the  system  was  abandoned 
the  sum  of  $15,589  was  outstanding.  Since  only  a  small 
percentage  of  this  was  collectible,  the  annual  average  net 
cost  per  capita  was  $1.50,  or  twenty  times  the  cost  to  the 
Cigar  Makers.  The  Leather  Workers  on  Horse  Goods 
loaned  during  the  seven  years  in  which  the  system  was  in 
operation  the  sum  of  $17,063.  The  annual  per  capita  ex- 
penditure was  57  cents,  and  the  loans  outstanding  when  the 
system  was  abolished  amounted  to  $2,526.  Thus  the  an- 
nual average  per  capita  cost  was  less  than  9  cents,  or  about 
the  same  as  that  of  the  Cigar  Makers.  In  the  Typographia, 
despite  the  fact  that  the  benefit  was  a  gift,  the  cost  was  very 
small.  During  the  twenty-four  years'  operation  of  the 
benefit  the  sum  of  $8,376  was  expended.  The  average  an- 
nual per  capita  cost  varied  from  10  cents  in  1907  to  61 
cents  in  1885  and  only  averaged  31  cents  for  the  entire 
period. 

The  following  tables  give  the  cost  and  other  financial 
details  of  the  systems  in  the  Cigar  Makers,  Typographia, 
Flint  Glass  Workers,  and  Leather  Workers  on  Horse 
Goods. 

94  Letter  to  the  writer,  October  19,  1915. 


UNION  AGENCIES  FOR  DISTRIBUTION  OF  WORKMEN 


105 


0  o  o  10  too 


M    <S    M  00    H-l    \Ti 


O  HI   O  O  *OHI   rf 

HI     HI     CS   V5 
tft 


M  00  VO  «   «O 


Amo 
Loan 


O 

VO  OO    M    l-i 

r^>-(  f^^ 
f«3  O  >OvO 


| 

d          ^  vp  «  Tj- to  Tj- •*?•  Tf  10  CO  >O  N  <O  CS  ro  CS 

k 

0< 

rC  CS  TJ-VO  Tj-  lOvO  t>.  rl-vO  tOrO<SCOfO~~~-.~- 

OfOi-iioOOONOvOCS'i-  Tj-vO  OO  ("-lOO^O  rO  HI  O  Tj-ioiO'i-tO 

5  OO  OO  IO  COvO  CS  O  i  ^OO  ONNO  CS  Tj-  r-—  O  O  O  OO  ^  n  IO  <S  M  OO  ^J 
2*  HI  O  0s-  O  VO  HI  OO  OO  O  ^"  ^"  t^»  ON  HI  O\  ON  rOVO  O  lO  O  HI  CO  HI  CO  O 
^3  nToo"  O^  H?  O~  lOvd"  rC  ^f  \O~  N"  d" 00*00"  ff  f^  i-Too"  ro  >O  10  tfoo"  fNToo"  TC 

M 

i  ^r^^oo^ 

Jg  §*        VO  OO  l>.00   ^*vN   N   fC>Ot>.iON   (>.(N|iO>Ot'5Hi   OvOp   ON  fi  PJ 

U  J      'M«itqf{M(|(j(«Mt|*<(«MM 

.1 

u  _ 

r*5  t>  HI  r^vO  N  ^fOrOflfJiOHi  M 

o         OO  r^vo'  IOCS  rf)iOHi  rj-O  rfiOCS  lOrt-  K.vO  r>.  (>.  ^J-00  N  T^  HI  oo 

O  r^oo  c*5  fCOO  fCOO  ON  T}-  HI  fj  f*5  r-~  >O  >O  l>.vO  fOfifJiOHi  N  (\|   _ 

oo  r^tOHivovooo  woo  tooNioi^Tf-Hivo  o  o  w  cs  MVO  «oiot^.rs 

CS  N  O  (>•  ONVO  HI  ONCS~rOr^fOr>-O~N   HI  rOONiO'frO^fiOWOO  >O 
HI  (N|  t/^  f/j  (s|   ff)  ^-  ^-  ^j-  f*j  i/}  Tj*vO   ^*  ^  TO  vN   CN|   CS   CO  *^"  ^  !O  lO  *O 

e     ** 
< 

O  HI  <NI  ro  «*•  lOvO  t^QO  ON  O  HI  cs  fO  ^  »OVO  r^.oo  ON  O  HI  cs  rO  ^*-  iO 

OO  OO  OO  OO  OO  OO  OO  OO  OO  00  ON  ON  ON  ON  ON  ON  ON  ON  ON  ON  O  O  O  O  O  O 
00  OO  00  OO  00  00  OO  00  OO  OO  00  OO  00  OO  OO  OO  00  OO  OO  OO 


IO6      UNEMPLOYMENT   AND   AMERICAN    TRADE   UNIONS 


•se  Goods 

Loans 
Outstanding 

>rkers  on  Ho 

Per  Capita 

r>. 

Leather  W< 

§"8 

o  S 

•  1 

CO 

I-H 

* 
vq 

(Np 

Workers 

Per  Capita 

10  r>.               up  (NJ  pj  M 

O 

Flint  Glais 

Amount 
Loaned 

OO     tN.                            OO     M     M  \O 

CO  ON                   CNJ  ^O   CO  H^ 
lO  lO                    rJ-OO   O  IO 
ON  O                     "5  O  W3  O 
CO  «O                     •<?  CNP  cT  •H' 

oq 

oo. 
rC 

1 

Per  Capita 

M  M  M 

M 

H 

i? 

O    (3 

N  0  0 

|/^S^     (^ 

t^  ^^  10 

•^-  O  lO 

q 

CO 

06" 
*«= 

0>?coJoco^NO>NO  co 

a 

w  co  ri-  >H  r>.  »ONO  oo  cs 

>p 

^g^gTS  2^J^g  £ 

1 

• 

a 

S 

N   Ot   M   ON  ON  ONOO  M   N 

O 

1 

b 

PU 



HH 

1 

a 

WOO   ^•cOt>-^t'"OO  M 

ON 

£ 

g 

HJ 

O  co  CO  OvOO  CO  CO  ^  r-* 
1/2NO   >-i  OO   M   rC  >->  NO  t~«- 
NO   O  NO  lOOO  IO  >^  CS   O 

S" 

o 

N 

Amoun 

O   O  NO   w   ONOO  CO  "5  "-I 

CO 
CO 

oo 

NO  I^^OO  ON  O  **^  f^  CO  ^T" 

oo 

1 

ON  ON  ON  ON  ON  ON  ON  ON  ON 

3 

1 
B 

{2 

> 

UNION  AGENCIES  FOR  DISTRIBUTION  OF  WORKMEN       IQJ 

In  conclusion,  there  are  certain  definite  hindrances  to  the 
movement  of  union  workmen  from  one  city  to  another  which 
very  largely  nullify  in  some  unions  the  attempts  to  promote 
a  better  distribution  of  labor.  As  has  already  been  noted, 
many  unions  have  delegated  to  their  local  unions  the  power 
to  fix  the  amount  of  the  initiation  fee.  They  have  also 
provided  that  a  member  transferring  to  a  local  union  in 
which  the  initiation  fee  is  greater  than  in  the  city  from 
which  the  member  transferred  must  pay  the  difference  be- 
fore his  card  is  accepted.  Members  of  the  Carpenters85 
and  Painters96  of  less  than  one  year's  standing  are  obliged 
to  pay  such  differences  when  they  travel  from  one  city  to 
another.  Since  some  local  unions  have  established  high 
initiation  fees  in  order  to  discourage  members  from  travel- 
ing, the  amount  to  be  paid  before  a  working  card  can  be 
obtained  is  sometimes  sufficient  to  dete'r  members  from 
transferring. 

Another  condition  which  operates  to  hinder  transference 
in  those  unions  which  have  only  local  systems  of  death  and 
sick  benefits,  is  that  a  member  transferring  from  one  local 
union  to  another  forfeits  all  claims  to  benefits  in  the  union 
from  which  he  goes  unless  he  pays  the  dues  and  assessments 
to  that  association,  and  does  not  become  a  beneficiary  in  the 
local  union  to  which  he  transfers  until  he  has  been  a  mem- 
ber for  a  certain  period,  generally  one  year. 

The  rules  governing  seniority  rights  and  privileges,  which 
were  discussed  in  a  previous  chapter,  have  a  marked  effect 
upon  the  transference  of  workmen.  Indeed,  in  some  unions 
this  system  has  made  traveling  a  negligible  factor.  Thus, 
President  Carter  of  the  Locomotive  Firemen  and  Engine- 
men  says  that  members  of  this  union  rarely  transfer  from 
one  place  to  another  or  from  one  company  to  another  unless 
they  are  among  the  last  on  the  list.97  A  member  who  has 
been  employed  by  a  railroad  for  several  years  has  usually 
secured  favorable  seniority  rights  and  when  laid  off  by  the 

95  Constitution,  1913,  sec.  106. 

96  Constitution,  1913,  sec.  50. 

97  Letter  to  the  writer,  October  19,  1915. 


IO8       UNEMPLOYMENT  AND  AMERICAN   TRADE   UNIONS 

company  on  account  of  depressed  business  conditions,  hesi- 
tates to  apply  for  employment  in  another  division  of  the 
road  or  to  another  company  because  his  seniority  rights 
would  not  be  recognized  and  he  would  be  compelled  to  start 
at  the  bottom  of  the  list,  thus  losing  all  he  had  gained  dur- 
ing his  former  employment.  Professor  Barnett  has  pointed 
out  how  the  priority  rights  of  the  Printers  have  operated  to 
decrease  mobility  of  labor  because  of  the  fact  that  the  most 
efficient  printer  can  not  transfer  his  priority  rights  from  one 
city  to  another  or  from  one  shop  to  another.98 

The  "permit"  system,  discussed  in  a  previous  chapter, 
was  shown  to  have  been  conceived  with  the  idea  of  controll- 
ing the  number  of  members  of  the  unions.  Although  this 
is  the  primary  reason  for  its  existence,  the  local  unions  have 
succeeded  in  utilizing  it  to  prevent  the  movement  of  mem- 
bers from  other  local  unions.  These  local  unions  when  in 
need  of  men  will  not  attempt  to  procure  experienced  work- 
men from  other  localities,  but  will  issue  permits  to  inex- 
perienced "handy  men."  The  local  unions  appreciate  the 
fact  that  after  employment  slackens  they  can  revoke  the 
permits  of  the  helpers,  but  where  they  have  secured  union 
members  from  other  cities  they  probably  could  not  get  rid 
of  them  when  employment  became  scarce.  This  phase  of 
the  permit  system  has  come  into  prominence  during  the  past 
few  years.  The  Elevator  Constructors  at  their  convention  in 
1904  provided  that  the  local  unions  should  apply  to  other 
cities  for  workmen  before  issuing  permits,"  but  it  appears 
that  this  rule  is  violated.  President  Murphy  recently  stated 
that  the  local  unions  favored  the  permit  system  principally 
because  they  could  provide  the  employers  with  sufficient 
men  without  procuring  members  from  other  cities.10*  The 
secretary  of  the  Brewery  Workers  has  said  that  the  local 
unions,  "  due  to  their  selfishness,"  used  permit  workmen  in 
time  of  prosperity  rather  than  apply  for  men  from  the 
nearby  cities.101 

88  Barnett,  The  Printers,  p.  241. 

99  Proceedings,  1904,  p.  7. 

100  Interview,  August,  1915. 

101  Proceedings,  1910,  p.  160. 


CHAPTER  V 
DISTRIBUTION  OF  EMPLOYMENT 

Unemployment  due  to  contraction  of  demand  may  be 
either  concentrated  upon  a  part  of  the  working  force,  or  be 
distributed  more  or  less  equally  among  the  entire  working 
force.  In  both  cases  the  aggregate  wages  will  be  the  same, 
and  the  total  amount  of  unemployment  will  not  have  been 
decreased.  The  difference  to  the  individual  workman,  how- 
ever, is  very  great.  It  is  obvious  that  if  an  employer  ex- 
pends two  dollars  for  labor,  it  would  be  socially  more  ad- 
vantageous to  divide  the  employment  between  two  other- 
wise unemployed  workmen  than  to  concentrate  it  upon  one 
of  them;  there  would  be  less  suffering  if  each  of  the  two 
had  one  dollar  than  if  one  man  possessed  the  two  dollars. 

It  must  be  realized,  however,  that  there  are  conditions  in 
particular  industries  which  tend  to  make  the  adoption  of 
such  a  policy  socially  injurious.  Thus,  the  longshoremen 
are  confronted  with  the  problem  of  having  the  work  dis- 
tributed among  too  great  a  number  of  workmen.  The  pol- 
icy has  also  been  disadvantageously  used  by  the  unions  in 
certain  trades  in  which  machinery  has  displaced  a  great 
number  of  workmen,  when  they  have  attempted  to  so  dis- 
tribute employment  as  to  maintain  the  original  working 
forces.1  In  such  cases  the  problem  is  different  and  the 
policy  of  equal  distribution  of  employment  is  open  to  criti- 
cism. But  where  the  contraction  of  demand  is  due  to  tem- 
porary fluctuations,  equal  distribution  of  employment  meets 
with  but  few  valid  objections. 

The  distribution  of  employment  is  accomplished  chiefly 
in  the  following  ways :  ( I )  Reduction  of  the  working  hours 
per  day  or  week  of  the  entire  force  of  workmen.  (2)  Di- 

1  Typographical  Journal,  March,  1915,  p.  456. 

109 


HO      UNEMPLOYMENT  AND  AMERICAN   TRADE  UNIONS 

vision  of  the  working  force  into  groups,  each  working  the 
normal  day  or  week  in  rotation.  (3)  Reduction  of  the 
working  hours  to  a  certain  point,  after  which  the  smaller 
amount  of  employment  is  met  by  a  dismissal  of  workmen. 
In  some  trades  one  of  these  methods  exists,  while  in  others 
two  or  three  of  them  are  found  side  by  side.  It  will  be 
the  aim  in  this  chapter  to  inquire  as  to  the  extent  to  which 
these  various  methods  are  utilized  in  the  more  highly  or- 
ganized trades  and  the  influence  of  the  union  in  bringing 
about  their  adoption. 

The  first  method — the  working  of  short  time — exists  as 
a  general  custom  in  the  following  unions:  United  Mine 
Workers,  Western  Federation  of  Miners,  Ladies  Garment 
Workers,  United  Garment  Workers,  Tailors,  Cloth  Hat 
and  Cap  Makers,  Textile  Workers,  Glove  Makers,  Hatters, 
Potters,  Flint  Glass  Workers,  and  Iron,  Steel  and  Tin 
Workers.  It  is  not  to  be  inferred  that  short  time  is  not 
used  in  other  unions,  because,  as  will  be  pointed  out  later, 
this  method  exists,  to  a  certain  extent,  in  almost  every  trade. 
But  it  is  only  in  the  unions  named  that  the  practice  is  in 
force  throughout  the  jurisdiction  of  the  unions. 

The  United  Mine  Workers  and  the  Western  Federation 
of  Miners  have  probably  a  more  effective  system  of  sharing 
work  than  that  practised  in  any  other  union.  When  the 
operator  has  secured  a  force  of  miners  sufficient  to  prop- 
erly work  his  mine  in  the  busy  season,  he  is  rarely  allowed 
to  reduce  this  number  on  account  of  a  slackened  demand 
for  coal.  He  is  obliged  to  give  to  every  workman  an  equal 
number  of  hours'  work  in  the  mine.  As  the  dull  season 
approaches,  he  reduces  the  number  of  days  to  be  worked 
each  week.  When  the  demand  for  coal  is  not  sufficient  to 
justify  the  working  of  a  full  day,  then  only  a  certain  num- 
ber of  hours  are  worked.  In  any  event,  each  workman 
must  be  given  the  same  number  of  hours  of  employment. 
In  consequence  of  these  demands  of  the  union  and  of  the 
seasonal  character  of  the  industry,  the  mines  are  idle  dur- 
ing many  days  of  the  year.  In  the  period  1900-1910  the 


DISTRIBUTION    OF   EMPLOYMENT  III 

number  of  idle  days  in  the  anthracite  fields  varied  from  71 
in  1910  to  184  in  1902,  and  in  the  bituminous  fields  from 
66  in  1907  to  107  in  I9o8.2  Although  this  system  was  gen- 
erally in  force  before  the  miners  became  strongly  organized, 
and  is  at  present  the  rule  in  a  number  of  non-union  mines, 
the  foremen  under  non-union  conditions  were  always  at  lib- 
erty to  discharge  a  man  when  a  reduction  of  the  working 
force  was  desired.  The  union  now  passes  judgment  upon 
discharges,  and  the  employer  must  prove  that  other  reasons 
than  the  desire  to  reduce  the  working  force  are  the  cause  of 
the  discharge. 

Not  only  does  the  union  demand  an  equal  distribution  of 
working  time,  but  "  every  mine  worker  shall  be  given  work 
in  his  turn  when  applying  for  same."3  Obviously,  the  fore- 
man might  allow  every  man  to  descend  into  the  mine,  but 
could  place  them  in  such  a  position  that  some  would  secure 
only  a  few  cars  each  day.  There  have  been  instances  where 
a  miner  stayed  in  the  mine  all  day  and  never  got  a  pit  car 
to  load.  The  rule  was  devised  not  to  equalize  the  miners' 
earnings  or  to  limit  the  output  but  to  give  every  man  an 
equal  opportunity  to  work.  In  mines  where  both  machine 
and  pick  miners  are  used  the  union  has  obtained  a  rule  that 
whenever  the  machines  are  operated  and  the  pick  miners 
not  employed,  "  such  turn  shall  be  given  that  will,  as  nearly 
as  possible,  equalize  the  earning  capacity  of  the  machine 
loaders  and  the  pick  miners."4 

Where  an  operator  closes  down  one  of  his  mines  and 
works  full  time  in  another,  the  union  has  not  attempted  to 
enforce  any  arrangement  by  which  those  unemployed 
through  the  closing  of  one  mine  may  share  in  the  working 
of  the  other ;  but  there  has  grown  up  in  many  mining  com- 
munities a  custom  under  which  the  work  is  divided.  John 
Mitchell  says  of  this  custom:  "This  system  of  dividing 

2  United  States  Geological  Survey :  Mineral  Resources  of  the 
United  States,  vol.  2,  1910,  p.  42. 

3 1913  Agreement,  Interstate  Movement  (Proceedings  of  the 
United  Mine  Workers,  1914,  p.  44). 

4  Machine  Scale  in  Arkansas  and  Oklahoma,  1912,  sec.  7,  in  Pro- 
ceedings of  the  United  Mine  Workers,  1914,  p.  71. 


112      UNEMPLOYMENT  AND  AMERICAN   TRADE   UNIONS 

employment  is  quite  general  in  mining  communities.  If  an 
employer  closes  down  one  of  his  mines  and  continues  others 
in  operation,  the  men  in  the  mine  that  is  working  will  invite 
their  fellow  unionists  where  work  has  been  stopped  to  share 
their  employment  with  them.  That  is  to  say,  the  men  who 
retain  their  jobs  will  remain  at  home  three  days  each  week, 
allowing  the  men  out  of  employment  to  take  their  places 
for  the  remaining  three  days."5 

These  various  rules  have  resulted  in  such  a  thorough- 
going distribution  of  employment  that  it  would  seem  as 
though  nothing  could  better  the  distribution  short  of  an  abso- 
lute limitation  on  daily  earnings.  It  has  been  suggested  that 
these  regulations  have  had  a  tendency  to  retain  so  great  a 
number  of  workmen  in  the  industry  that  the  earnings  are 
not  sufficient  for  proper  living  conditions.  On  the  other 
hand,  the  conditions  surrounding  the  industry  are  such  that 
a  greater  number  of  workmen  are  needed  at  certain  seasons. 
In  the  anthracite  fields,  production  is  more  nearly  regular 
throughout  the  year  in  consequence  of  a  sliding  scale  of 
prices  to  the  consumer,  while  in  the  bituminous  fields  the 
coal  can  only  be  mined  as  needed,  because  the  atmospheric 
effects  upon  this  grade  of  coal  are  such  that  for  domestic 
purposes  it  must  be  consumed  shortly  after  it  is  mined. 
Consequently,  in  the  winter  months  there  is  needed  a  rela- 
tively larger  force  of  bituminous  than  of  anthracite  miners. 

The  most  significant  case  in  which  the  policy  of  the  unions 
towards  the  question  at  issue  is  revealed  is  in  the  garment 
industry.  Since  the  signing  of  the  agreement  in  1911  be- 
tween the  Ladies  Garment  Workers  and  the  employers  of 
New  York,  the  distribution  of  employment  has  been  one  of 
the  chief  contentions  between  the  union  and  the  employers' 
association.  During  the  first  nine  months  of  the  operation 
of  the  Protocol  186  of  the  998  grievances  submitted  to  the 
Board  of  Grievances  were  alleged  discriminations  in  the 
distribution  of  work.  From  September  to  December,  1911, 
53  of  the  295  grievances  were  of  the  same  character.6 

6  The  Bridgemen's  Magazine,  January,  1910,  p.  12. 
6  Bulletin  of  the  Bureau  of  Labor,  No.  98,  p.  230. 


DISTRIBUTION   OF   EMPLOYMENT  113 

Previous  to  1911,  when  the  workmen  were  poorly  organ- 
ized, the  employer  allowed  the  foreman  in  each  department 
to  distribute  the  work  as  best  suited  him.  In  one  factory, 
the  question  of  race  decided  who  was  to  get  the  lion's  share 
of  the  work ;  in  another,  it  was  a  question  of  favoritism  or, 
perhaps,  a  bribe  to  the  foreman.  Some  piece  workers  were 
allowed  to  work  the  entire  day  and  far  into  the  night,  while 
others,  who  were  reporting  each  day  to  the  factory,  were 
refused  any  employment.  To  remedy  these  conditions,  the 
Ladies  Garment  Workers  Union  insisted  in  the  conferences 
preliminary  to  the  signing  of  the  Protocol  upon  a  more 
equitable  distribution  of  employment,  and  secured  a  rule 
which  requires  the  employer  to  divide  employment,  as  far 
as  possible,  among  all  regular  piece  and  time  workers. 

The  distribution  takes  the  form  of  either  short  time  or 
rotation  of  the  workers.  The  manufacturers  do  not  object 
strenuously  to  the  application  of  this  rule  to  piece  workers, 
but  have,  by  many  subterfuges,  attempted  to  evade  its  ap- 
plication to  time  workers.  The  difficulty  has  been  the  in- 
terpretation of  the  term  "regular  workmen."  The  union 
contends  that  this  includes  all  who  have  been  working  for 
the  employer,  while  the  manufacturers  claim  that  it  only 
includes  those  who  are  employed  during  the  slack  seasons 
and  does  not  include  those  taken  on  during  the  rush  periods. 
In  December,  1914,  this  question  was  submitted  to  the  Board 
of  Arbitration  in  the  Cloak,  Suit  and  Skirt  Industry  of  New 
York.  The  Chairman,  Mr.  Louis  D.  Brandeis,  gave  the 
following  decision :  "  Equal  division  of  work  is  to  be  re- 
garded as  desirable  and  as  necessary  in  this  industry ;  for  it 
must  be  acknowledged  that  it  should  be  made  possible  for 
the  people  called  into  the  industry,  and  who  are  regularly 
employed  therein,  to  earn  a  reasonable  livelihood."  But  as 
to  what  constituted  a  "  regular "  workman,  the  Board  re- 
fused to  give  an  interpretation,  merely  saying  that  this  ques- 
tion "  must  be  left  to  the  judgment  of  men  familiar  with 
the  particular  facts,  because  the  facts  will  vary  in  par- 
8 


114      UNEMPLOYMENT   AND   AMERICAN    TRADE   UNIONS 

ticular  cases."7  Aside  from  this  disputed  question,  the  fifty 
thousand  union  ladies  garment  workers  of  New  York  are 
working  under  rules  guaranteeing  them  a  fairly  equal  dis- 
tribution of  employment.  In  the  Boston  Protocol  of  1913," 
and  in  the  Philadelphia  Protocol  of  I9I4,9  the  union  secured 
provisions  for  an  equal  distribution  of  work  among  its 
members.  In  other  cities  both  the  agreements  with  the  em- 
ployers' associations  and  with  individual  manufacturers  pro- 
vide for  an  equal  division  of  employment. 

The  United  Garment  Workers  and  the  Tailors  have  in- 
sisted at  all  times  upon  an  equal  distribution  of  work  among 
their  members,  but  they  have  not  met  with  the  same  success 
as  the  Ladies  Garment  Workers,  doubtless  on  account  of 
the  lack  of  general  agreements  with  employers'  associations. 
In  their  agreements  with  individual  manufacturers,  these 
unions  have  generally  obtained  an  equal  distribution  of  em- 
ployment among  the  regular  workmen ;  but  with  regard 
to  what  constitutes  a  regular  employee,  and  as  to  when  the 
workmen  may  be  discharged  on  account  of  the  reorganiza- 
tion of  the  factory,  the  unions  and  the  employers  have  not 
been  able  to  agree.  Differences  on  these  points  have  led  to 
many  strikes  in  the  clothing  industry.  In  Baltimore,  in  Au- 
gust, 1912,  three  hundred  men  went  on  strike  because  the 
firm  insisted  upon  laying  off  a  pocket  maker  instead  of  dis- 
tributing the  work  among  the  fourteen  members  in  this  par- 
ticular department.  In  1914  another  Baltimore  employer 
attempted  to  discharge  a  certain  number  of  men  on  account 
of  "  a  reorganization  of  the  factory."  In  this  case  the  union 
asked  for  a  distribution  of  the  work,  which  the  employers 
refused  and  the  consequence  was  a  strike  involving  two 
thousand  men.  Wherever  possible,  the  unions  have  at- 
tempted to  induce  the  employers  to  work  short  time  instead 
of  discharging  a  portion  of  the  working  force,  and  they  have 
recently  secured  the  acceptance  of  this  policy  by  many 
employers. 

7  Ladies  Garment  Worker,  February,  1915,  pp.  11-14. 
1  Ibid.,  May,  1913,  p.  17. 

8  Ibid.,  October,  1914,  p.  12. 


DISTRIBUTION    OF   EMPLOYMENT  115 

The  Cloth  Hat  and  Cap  Makers  have  always  insisted 
upon  the  employment  in  the  dull  seasons  of  all  members  who 
were  in  the  working  force  in  the  busy  season.  The  union 
has  secured  the  establishment  of  this  policy  in  all  shops 
where  the  workmen  are  paid  piece  wages,  but  has  been  un- 
able to  enforce  it  in  the  shops  where  time  wages  are  paid.10 
The  Textile  Workers  Union  recently  demanded  the  incor- 
poration in  their  agreements  with  the  manufacturers  of  an 
article  providing  for  equal  distribution  of  employment. 
There  was  but  little  opposition,  and  the  movement  has  been 
generally  successful.  Even  in  non-union  establishments  the 
manufacturers  have  followed  this  policy  for  many  years, 
although  they  do  not  always  include  the  entire  working 
force,  and  sometimes  leave  certain  employees  out  of  the  dis- 
tribution. 

The  Glove  Makers,  in  all  of  their  agreements  with  the 
employers,  have  secured  provision  for  an  equal  distribution 
of  employment  in  the  dull  seasons.  The  employers  are  re- 
quired to  give  to  each  piece  worker  not  the  same  number  of 
pieces  but  work  which  will  yield  equal  wages.11  While  there 
is  no  written  agreement  between  the  Hatters  and  their  em- 
ployers as  to  the  distribution  of  work  in  slack  periods,  there 
is,  as  President  Lawlor  terms  it,  "  a  gentleman's  agreement " 
that  short  time  will  be  worked  in  the  dull  months,  and  no 
employee  may  be  laid  off  on  account  of  such  dullness.12 
One  of  the  chief  contentions  in  the  great  Danbury  lockout 
of  1890  was  over  the  distribution  of  work.  The  manu- 
facturers claimed  that  they  should  be  allowed  to  regulate 
the  distribution  of  employment,  while  the  union  claimed  an 
equal  division  of  work.13  Since  that  time,  with  but  few  ex- 
ceptions, the  policy  of  equal  distribution  of  employment 
among  the  entire  working  force  has  been  accepted  in  full  by 
the  employers. 

10  Interview  with  Secretary  Zuckerman,  August,  1915. 

11  Interview  with  Secretary  Christman,  August,  1915. 

12  Interview,  August,  1915. 

18  The  Sixth  Annual  Report  of  the  Connecticut  Bureau  of  Labor 
Statistics,  Part  V,  p.  191. 


Il6      UNEMPLOYMENT   AND   AMERICAN    TRADE   UNIONS 

If  the  policy  of  equal  distribution  of  employment  is  to  be 
generally  enforced  in  a  trade,  there  is  need  for'  a  strong 
organization  of  employers  to  deal  with  that  of  the  workmen. 
In  every  trade  there  are  certain  employers  who  will  accede 
to  the  demands  of  the  union  for  the  distribution  of  work; 
but  there  are  also  others  who,  although  they  may  agree  to 
the  standard  rate,  the  normal  day,  and  union  working  condi- 
tions, will  not  readily  relinquish  their  right  to  hire  and  dis- 
charge as  they  see  fit.  Consequently,  there  is  a  greater 
likelihood  of  finding  the  system  of  equal  distribution  of  em- 
ployment widely  enforced  in  those  trades  where  the  associa- 
tions of  employers  and  workmen  hold  conferences  and  make 
agreements  for  the  entire  trade.  The  most  striking  ex- 
amples of  systems  of  this  kind  are  in  the  pottery  and  glass 
industries. 

The  National  Brotherhood  of  Operative  Potters  for  many- 
years  unsuccessfully  attempted  to  obtain  the  consent  of  the 
United  States  Potters'  Association— the  manufacturers  of 
general  ware — to  incorporating  in  the  agreements  a  rule 
requiring  equal  distribution  of  work  among  all  employees. 
At  the  conference  in  1911  the  manufacturers  agreed  to  adopt 
this  rule  and  to  work  short  time  in  the  slack  seasons,  instead 
of  continuing  the  practice  of  concentrating  the  work  upon 
those  favored  by  the  foreman.14  The  union  also  secured 
from  the  Sanitary  Manufacturing  Potters'  Association  at 
the  conference  in  1912  a  rule  similar  to  that  in  force  in  the 
general  ware  department,  except  that  the  work  was  to  be 
divided  equally  among  workmen  making  the  same  class  of 
ware.18  For  instance,  if  a  manufacturer  were  to  close  en- 
tirely the  lavatory  ware  department  of  his  factory  and  retain 
jet  makers  at  full  time,  the  pressers  in  the  former  depart- 
ment would  not  share  in  the  work.  To  this  the  union 
strongly  objected,  maintaining  that  as  "the  pressers  are  at 

14  Agreement  between  the  United  States  Potters'  Association  and 
the  National  Brotherhood  of  Operative  Potters,  Atlantic  City,  New 
Jersey,  1911,  sec.  n. 

15  Agreement  between  the  Sanitary  Manufacturing  Potters'  Asso- 
ciation and  the  National  Brotherhood  of  Operative  Potters,   1912, 
p.  i. 


DISTRIBUTION   OF   EMPLOYMENT  117 

all  times  expected  and,  in  fact,  compelled  to  make  any  kind 
of  articles  given  them,"  the  work  of  the  entire  plant  should 
be  equally  divided  among  all  those  competent  to  do  it.18 
The  Potters  on  several  occasions  have  struck  to  enforce  the 
rule  requiring  an  equal  distribution  of  work.  For  example, 
in  March,  1914,  the  pressers  in  one  of  the  Trenton  potteries 
struck  because  several  pressers  had  been  discharged  by  the 
firm  on  the  ground  that  the  force  was  larger  than  was 
needed.17  In  April  of  the  same  year  the  pressers  in  a  pottery 
at  Mannington,  West  Virginia,  went  on  strike  for  reasons 
connected  with  the  rule.18 

In  the  Flint  Glass  Workers'  Union  the  necessity  for  some 
rule  under  which  its  members  might  be  guaranteed  more 
continuous  employment  was  early  recognized.  Glass  fac- 
tories do  not  produce  at  maximum  capacity  during  more 
than  six  or  eight  months  even  in  the  most  prosperous  years. 
In  1897  President  Smith  said  that  the  existing  custom  was 
for  the  employers  to  lay  off  a  certain  number  of  their  work- 
men when  trade  slackened,  and  to  retain  on  full  time  those 
who  stood  highest  in  the  estimation  of  the  foreman.  Almost 
invariably  the  slow  workers,  or  those  who  "had  suggested 
that  the  employees  have  rights  that  should  be  respected," 
were  among  those  laid  off.  This  custom,  in  the  opinion  of 
the  president,  was  so  strongly  entrenched  in  the  trade  by 
long  usage  that  there  was  great  doubt  as  to  the  possibility 
of  establishing  any  better  system.19  However,  the  conven- 
tion of  that  year  proposed  that  all  departments  should 
attempt  to  induce  the  employers  to  distribute  fairly  the 
work.20  Since  then  each  of  the  sixteen  departments  of  the 
industry,  at  their  conferences  with  the  employers,  have  ob- 
tained rules  providing  for  an  equal  distribution  of  work. 
Most  of  the  agreements  provide  for  distribution  among  all 
who  are  found  competent,  regardless  of  the  class  of  work 

16  Proceedings,  1914,  pp.  76-77. 

17  Potters'  Herald,  March  26,  1914,  p.  2. 

18  Ibid.,  April  23,  1914. 

18  Proceedings,  1897,  pp.  57-58. 
20  Ibid.,  1897,  p.  175. 


Il8      UNEMPLOYMENT   AND   AMERICAN    TRADE   UNIONS 

at  which  they  were  formerly  employed.  The  cutters  and 
mould  makers,  however,  have  less  stringent  rules.  In  the 
former  department,  the  employer  is  allowed  in  a  period  of 
slackness  to  lay  off  the  men  engaged  during  a  rush  period, 
provided  such  employment  was  for  less  than  four  weeks.21 
In  the  Mould  Making  Department  an  employer  is  required 
to  share  the  work  among  all  the  working  force  except  work- 
men who  have  not  held  their  positions  for  six  months.22 

The  rule  has  led  to  many  disputes  between  the  employers 
and  the  union,  and  even  between  different  factions  in  the 
union.  The  controversies  became  so  numerous  that  at  the 
conference  in  1911  between  the  manufacturers  and  the  union 
the  interpretation  of  the  rule  was  brought  up  for  settlement. 
The  conclusion  which  was  reached  in  conference  was  re- 
jected on  reference  by  both  the  manufacturers  and  the 
union.  The  only  provision  which  was  accepted  by  both 
parties  was  that  "  whenever  the  necessity  for  a  division  of 
time  arises,  the  factory  committee  and^the  management  shall 
agree  on  a  satisfactory  division."23 

In  the  iron  and  steel  industries,  the  practice  of  working 
short  time  in  periods  of  depression  has  become  a  generally 
accepted  policy  in  many  union  and  non-union  mills.  How- 
ever, the  manufacturers  have  frequently  used  other  means 
of  curtailing  production,  such  as  running  single  instead  of 
double  turn,  and  of  closing  a  certain  number  of  their  fur- 
naces. The  Iron,  Steel  and  Tin  Workers'  Union  adopted 
in  1886  the  following  rule  to  cover  such  cases :  "  Should 
any  department  of  a  mill  be  stopped  running  single  or  double 
turn,  through  over-production,  or  other  causes,  the  work 
shall  be  equally  divided,  except  where  a  furnace  is  out  for 
repairs."2*  The  union  has  also  provided  that  any  mill, 
running  double  or  triple  turns  during  three  or  more  months 
of  the  year,  shall  be  considered  a  double  turn  mill,  and  in 
the  event  of  such  a  mill  going  on  single  time,  the  work  shall 

"  -7* 

Proceedings,  1913,  p.  216. 

22  Proceedings,  1912,  p.  167. 

83  Proceedings,  1912,  p.  97. 

24  Proceedings,  1886,  p.  1851. 


DISTRIBUTION    OF   EMPLOYMENT  119 

be  divided  equally  among  the  different  crews.25  For  many 
years,  through  the  influence  of  the  members  who  were  hold- 
ing regular  positions,  this  rule  was  not  obeyed  by  many  of 
the  local  lodges.  There  was  also  disagreement  as  to  the 
proper  method  of  dividing  the  work.  Various  plans  were 
adopted.  In  some  mills  the  men  worked  in  rotation,  while 
in  others  three  and  four  shifts  were  worked.  In  the  period 
of  depression  from  1893  to  l^9^  tne  m^s  worked  short  time, 
but  did  not  employ  the  men  laid  off  on  account  of  the  closing 
of  certain  furnaces.  President  Garland  of  the  Amalga- 
mated Association  advocated  the  adoption  of  a  three-shift 
system  and  it  appears  that  this  plan  was  put  into  effect  in 
many  mills,  for  the  president  reported  to  the  convention  in 
1898  that  seventy-five  per  cent  of  the  members  were  then 
working  under  the  three-shift  system.26  At  the  convention 
of  1900  several  lodges  asked  for  the  privilege  of  working 
four  shifts  in  order  to  help  the  great  number  of  unemployed, 
but  they  were  advised  to  divide  the  work  in  some  other 
manner.27  During  1901  many  lodges  reported  that  they  had 
formed  floating  crews  from  those  who  had  worked  at 
furnaces  which  were  then  idle,  and  allowed  them  to  work  in 
rotation  with  the  regular  crews.28  This  method  was  sug- 
gested to  the  American  Tinplate  Company  by  President 
Garland  when  he  went  to  New  York  in  1901  to  plead  the 
cause  of  the  unemployed.29  At  present  the  manufacturers 
and  the  union  have  agreed  that,  in  all  cases,  the  work  shall  be 
distributed  among  all  of  the  workmen,  except  those  who 
have  not  been  members  of  the  union  for  thirty  days. 

The  general  trade  agreement  between  the  Glass  Bottle 
Blowers  and  the  employers  provides  for  the  employment  of 
idle  men  by  changing  the  factory  from  a  two  to  a  three 
shift  system  in  dull  seasons.  When  this  is  not  practicable, 
the  shop  committee  and  the  manufacturer  are  to  arrange 

25  Constitution,  1913,  art.  17,  sec.  6. 

26  Proceedings,  1898,  p.  5418. 

27  Proceedings,  1900,  p.  5839. 

28  Amalgamated  Journal,  February  14,  1901,  p.  18. 

29  Ibid.,  p.  20. 


I2O      UNEMPLOYMENT  AND  AMERICAN   TRADE   UNIONS 

some  other  method  for  an  equal  division  of  employment 
among  the  workmen.30  In  consequence  of  the  introduction 
of  automatic  machinery,  the  three-shift  system  has  been 
widely  established  as  the  normal  arrangement  throughout 
the  year.  Where  this  is  the  case  the  distribution  of  work  on 
account  of  seasonal  variations  must  be  accomplished  in  some 
other  manner.  Another  rule  agreed  to  by  the  manufacturers 
provided  that  when  a  majority  of  blowers  in  a  factory  agree 
to  do  so,  the  work  may  be  divided  among  all.  It  appears, 
however,  that  this  rule  is  enforced  in  only  a  small  part  of 
the  factories.  President  Hayes  in  1908  referred  to  several 
instances  in  which  the  local  unions  had  asked  for  an  equal 
distribution  of  employment  and  the  employers  had  acceded 
to  their  request,  but  many  of  the  local  unions  did  not  avail 
themselves  of  this  opportunity.31  At  the  convention  in  1914 
President  Hayes  urged  the  members  to  pay  more  attention 
to  this  provision,32  but  it  appeared  that  some  of  the  members 
were  not  in  favor  of  dividing  work  because  of  its  tendency 
to  keep  in  the  trade  more  men  than  necessary. 

As  stated  above,  there  are  very  few  trades  outside  of  the 
building  trades,83  in  which  short  time  is  not  worked  in  par- 
ticular cases.  The  practice  (is  found  among  the  Stove 
Mounters,  Paper  Makers,  Coopers,  Leather  Workers  on 
Horse  Goods,  Metal  Polishers,  Lithographers,  Boot  and 
Shoe  Workers,  Photo-Engravers,  Lace  Operatives,  Laundry 
Workers,  in  the  stove  branch  of  the  Iron  Molders,  and  to 
a  less  extent,  among  the  Bakers,  Bookbinders,  Pattern 
Makers,  Commercial  Telegraphers,  and  the  Street  Railway 
Employees. 

The  second  method  by  which  employment  is  distributed — 
the  system  of  rotation — is  less  prevalent  than  the  working 

so  Wage  Scale  and  Working  Rules,  Glass  Vial  and  Bottle  List,  for 
the  Blast  of  1913-1914,  sec.  14,  p.  76. 

81  Proceedings,  1908,  p.  54. 

82  Proceedings,  1914,  p.  109. 

83  An  exception  in  the  building  trades  appears  to  be  the  Granite 
Cutters.    On  several  occasions  some  of  the  local  unions  have  pro- 
vided for  a  temporary  shortening  of  the  working  day  from  eight  to 
six  hours,  in  order  to  provide  work  for  the  unemployed.     For  ex- 
ample, see  Granite  Cutters'  Journal,  April,  1915,  p.  4. 


DISTRIBUTION    OF   EMPLOYMENT  121 

of  short  time.  When  the  charges  for  lighting,  heating, 
superintendence,  etc.,  are  fairly  constant  whether  the  em- 
ployer is  working  his  full  force  or  only  a  portion  of  it,  it  is 
obvious  that  it  would  be  a  considerable  saving  were  he  to 
operate  his  plant  on  part  time  with  the  full  force,  instead  of 
operating  full  time  with  a  portion  of  the  force.  On  the 
other  hand,  when  conditions  in  the  industry  are  such  that  it 
is  necessary  to  maintain  an  average  daily  output  in  the  dull 
season,  or  when  it  is  economical  to  keep  a  portion  of  the 
machinery  in  operation  continuously,  the  method  of  rota- 
tion is  more  advantageous  to  the  employer  than  the  working 
of  short  time. 

These  considerations  are  well  illustrated  in  the  case  of 
the  Brewery  Workers.  Here  the  manufacturers  desire  the 
uninterrupted  operation  of  their  breweries  on  account  of  con- 
ditions growing  out  of  the  methods  of  brewing  and  out  of 
the  regularity  of  sales  of  their  product.  For  many  years 
prior  to  the  formation  of  a  strong  organization  among  the 
brewery  workers,  the  employers  generally  met  the  slack 
season  by  a  dismissal  of  a  part  of  their  working  forces.  In- 
asmuch as  this  frequently  resulted  in  the  laying  off  of  one 
half  of  the  force,  the  organized  workers  demanded  a  more 
equitable  distribution  of  employment  during  the  winter 
months.  By  1901  the  demands  of  the  union  had  resulted 
in  the  incorporation  in  the  majority  of  agreements  with  the 
employers  of  a  rule  requiring  an  equal  distribution  of  work 
among  the  entire  working  force  in  the  slack  season.  The 
secretary  reported  to  the  convention  in  1901  that  "almost 
every  contract  now  contains  a  clause  providing  that  during 
the  slack  times  in  winter,  comrades  shall  be  laid  off  alter- 
nately for  a  week  at  a  time.34  Employers  of  large  brew- 
eries have  only  occasionally  objected  to  this  method  of  meet- 
ing seasonal  fluctuations,  but  in  small  breweries  the  union 
has  always  had  to  struggle  for  the  acceptance  of  the  rule. 
There  are  usually  only  a  few  thoroughly  competent  brewers 
in  a  small  brewery,  and  their  work  is  divided  in  such  a  man- 

34  Proceedings,  1901,  p.  49. 


122       UNEMPLOYMENT   AND   AMERICAN    TRADE    UNIONS 

ner  that  when  some  of  them  are  laid  off  the  efficiency  of 
the  working  force  is  greatly  impaired.  To  meet  this  condi- 
tion, the  union  has  conceded  that  short  time  may  be  worked 
in  those  breweries  where  rotation  is  impracticable.  Even 
where  the  system  of  rotation  is  practised,  the  union  has  in- 
sisted on  a  reduction  in  working  hours  from  nine  during 
the  busy  season  to  eight  in  the  winter,  and  has  prohibited 
the  working  of  any  overtime  when  the  men  are  working 
short  time  or  in  rotation. 

The  adoption  of  these  methods  of  meeting  seasonal  fluc- 
tuations in  the  brewery  industry  is  due  to  the  constant 
struggle  of  the  union.  As  the  general  secretary  has  said, 
"the  master  brewers  have  worked  tooth  and  nail  to  eradi- 
cate the  lay-off  clauses  in  the  agreements."35  Recently  the 
members  of  the  union  in  Washington,  D.  C,  and  Wilming- 
ton, Delaware,  have  been  locked  out  because  of  their  in- 
sistence upon  an  equal  distribution  of  employment.  In 
Washington  the  employers  wished  to  discharge  a  certain 
percentage  of  the  workmen  and  to  divide  the  employment 
among  the  remaining  working  force ;  but  the  union  refused 
to  accede  to  anything  except  a  division  of  the  work  among 
the  original  working  forces.36  Secretary  Proebstle  of  the 
Brewery  Workers  says  that  the  union  attaches  the  same  im- 
portance to  the  question  of  distribution  of  employment  as  it 
does  to  wages  and  hours,  for  without  the  maintenance  of 
this  policy,  the  workmen  would  be  unable  to  provide  proper 
living  conditions.37 

The  Amalgamated  Glass  Workers'  Union  compels  its  sub- 
ordinate local  unions  to  insert  in  their  agreements  with  the 
employers  a  clause  providing  for  an  equal  distribution  of 
work  in  the  slack  season.38  This  generally  takes  the  form 
of  rotation,  although  in  several  cases,  as  for  example,  in 
the  1914  agreement  with  the  employers  of  Cincinnati,  Ohio, 

35  Reports  of  the  General  Secretary-Treasurer  in  the  Proceedings, 
1903,  P.  157- 

86  For  a  complete  description  of  the  lockout,  see  Brauerei-Arbeiter 
Zeitung,  April,  1915. 

57  Interview,  August,  1915. 

88  Constitution,  1913,  sec.  151. 


DISTRIBUTION    OF   EMPLOYMENT  123 

it  is  provided  that  "  in  dull  times  the  working  hours  shall  be 
reduced  so  as  to  give  each  member  employed  an  equal 
amount  of  working  time."39  Several  of  the  unions  char- 
tered by  the  American  Federation  of  Labor,  such  as  the 
Crown  Cork  and  Seal  Operatives,  and  the  Watch  Case 
Engravers,  provide  for  rotation  in  the  dull  seasons,  and,  as 
has  been  pointed  out  above,  the  Ladies'  Garment  Workers, 
the  Iron,  Steel  and  Tin  Workers,  the  Glass  Bottle  Blowers, 
and  the  Flint  Glass  Workers  combine  the  method  of  rota- 
tion and  the  method  of  short-time. 

The  third  method  by  which  distribution  of  employment 
is  accomplished — short  time  to  meet  a  slight  fluctuation,  but 
dismissal  of  workmen  to  meet  a  longer  fluctuation — is  very 
common.  It  is  obvious  that  this  method  will  be  preferred 
in  those  trades  in  which  it  is  particularly  desirable  to  retain 
the  most  valuable  workmen.  In  the  mechanical  depart- 
ments of  the  railroads  and,  in  fact,  in  the  majority  of  shops 
where  members  of  the  Boilermakers,  Machinists,  Iron 
Molders,  Blacksmiths,  Metal  Polishers,  Sheet  Metal  Work- 
ers, and  Pattern  Makers  are  employed,  this  method  is  in 
general  practice.  A  typical  agreement  is  that  between  the 
Rock  Island  Federated  Trades  and  the  Chicago,  Rock  Is- 
land and  Pacific  Railway,  as  follows :  "  When  reducing  ex- 
penses, the  full  force  of  men  will  be  retained,  and  reduction 
made  in  hours  until  the  number  of  hours  shall  have  reached 
forty  per  week ;  but  any  further  reduction  will  be  made  by 
laying  off  men,  seniority  and  ability  to  govern."40  Occa- 
sionally the  reverse  of  this  method  is  employed;  that  is,  a 
slight  fluctuation  is  met  by  a  dismissal  of  workmen,  while 
any  further  fluctuation  is  provided  for  by  the  working  of 
short  time.  This  is  less  likely  to  meet  the  approval  of  the 
workmen,  but  is  more  advantageous  to  the  employers  in  that 
they  are  enabled  to  dismiss  the  less  efficient  at  the  first 
opportunity. 

The  "  five-day  "  rule  of  some  of  the  local  unions  of  the 

8B  Agreement  between  the  Cincinnati,   Ohio,   local  union  of  the 
Amalgamated  Glass  Workers  and  the  employers,  1914,  art.  6,  sec.  i. 
40  Boilermakers'  Journal,  February,  1912,  p.  107. 


124      UNEMPLOYMENT  AND  AMERICAN   TRADE  UNIONS 

Typographical  Union  is  an  interesting  example  of  this 
method.  This  rule  has  grown  out  of  the  "six-day-law" 
which  was  discussed  in  a  previous  chapter.  Its  operation 
is  limited  to  seasonal  fluctuations  and  periods  of  general 
industrial  depression.  Under  the  rule,  those  who  are  regu- 
larly employed  are  obliged  to  give  to  the  unemployed  the 
opportunity  to  work  one  day  each  week,  the  regular  force 
being  limited  to  five  days  employment.  The  employers  have 
strenuously  objected  to  this  rule  and  a  number  of  local 
unions  that  have  adopted  it  in  periods  of  unemployment 
have  been  forced  to  abandon  it,  either  because  the  unem- 
ployed were  attracted  from  other  cities,  or  because  of  the 
employers'  objections.41  When  on  December  27,  1914,  the 
1 80  printers  employed  in  the  three  newspaper  plants  of  New 
Orleans  were  locked  out,  one  of  the  important  contentions 
was  that  the  local  union  had  passed  a  rule  compelling  its 
members  to  share  all  work  beyond  forty  hours  per  week 
with  the  unemployed.42  The  employers  declared  that  the 
local  union  had  abrogated  the  contract  existing  between  the 
employers  and  the  union  "  by  passing  and  arbitrarily  putting 
into  effect  a  five-day  law  in  our  several  offices,"  thus  "  dis- 
turbing the  working  conditions  therein  at  an  increase  of 
expense  to  the  publishers  and  a  decrease  of  the  efficiency  of 
their  respective  composing  rooms."43  The  five-day  rule  is 
found  to  a  limited  extent  in  some  other  unions,  as  for  in- 
stance, in  many  local  unions  of  the  Bakers  during  the  dull 
seasons. 

Despite  the  wide  prevalence  of  systems  of  distribution, 
the  commonest  means  of  reducing  the  production  of  the 
working  force  is  to  discharge  part  of  the  force.  This 
method  not  only  exists  among  the  unskilled  and  the  unor- 
ganized, but  in  well-organized  and  skilled  trades.  It  is  the 
almost  universal  custom  among  the  thousands  of  workmen 
in  the  building  trades  and  is  accepted  by  many  of  the  strong- 
est unions.  Such  strong  unions  as  the  Printers  and  the 

41  Barnett,  The  Printers,  p.  225. 
12  Typographical  Journal,  March,  1915,  p.  344. 
48  Ibid.,  February,  1915,  p.  174. 


DISTRIBUTION    OF   EMPLOYMENT  125 

Railroad  Brotherhoods  in  their  agreements  with  employers 
concede  to  the  latter  the  absolute  right  to  discharge  as  many 
as  they  please  in  the  dull  seasons,  merely  asking  that  the 
seniority  rights  of  the  workmen  be  respected.  Thus,  the 
majority  of  the  members  of  the  American  unions,  it  may  be 
safely  said,  are  not  affected  by  rules  which  provide  for  a 
distribution  of  employment. 

In  view  of  the  widely  varying  practices  of  the  unions,  it 
is  pertinent  to  inquire  what  are  the  differences  among  the 
trades  and  industries  which  lead  to  these  differences  in 
trade-union  policy.  Broadly  speaking  these  trade  charac- 
teristics are  as  follows : 

1 i )  The  greater  differences  in  efficiency  among  workmen 
in  one  trade  than  in  another. 

(2)  The  greater  value,  other  than  general  efficiency,  of 
certain  workmen  to  a  particular  employer. 

(3)  The  greater  expense  and  difficulty  incurred  in  re- 
cruiting the  working  force  in  the  busy  seasons. 

(4)  Differences  in  the  factors  affecting  overhead  charges. 

i.  The  first  set  of  factors  is,  without  doubt,  the  dominat- 
ing influence  in  the  greater  number  of  cases.  The  capacity 
of  workmen  varies  considerably  in  some  trades.  The  ex- 
tent of  this  difference  depends  chiefly  upon  the  character  of 
the  trade,  it  being  greater  in  those  cases  where  the  skill  of 
the  workman  is  the  controlling  factor  in  production.  Inas- 
much as  the  members  of  unions  are  employed  at  standard 
rates,  and  as  this  minimum  has  generally  become  the  maxi- 
mum, the  employer  is  usually  paying  different  wage  rates 
per  unit  of  efficiency  to  his  various  workmen.  Therefore, 
when  an  employer  is  forced  to  curtail  production,  it  is  more 
economical  for  him  to  dismiss  those  workmen  who  are  less 
competent  than  to  retain  the  entire  force  either  on  short- 
time  or  in  rotation.  The  differentiation  in  favor  of  the 
more  competent  is,  of  course,  greater  in  those  trades  where 
time- wages  are  paid.  It  is  therefore  to  be  expected  that 
the  dismissal  of  workmen  in  the  slack  seasons  will  be  found 
more  frequently  where  time-wages  are  paid,  and  that  short- 


126      UNEMPLOYMENT   AND   AMERICAN   TRADE   UNIONS 

time  and  rotation  will  be  more  common  in  industries  where 
piece-wages  are  paid.  Of  the  twelve  unions  whose  mem- 
bers work  short-time  in  periods  of  seasonal  and  cyclical 
fluctuations,  ten  are  in  trades  paying  piece- wages ;  and  one 
of  the  two  unions  whose  members  work  in  rotation  in  the 
dull  seasons  is  a  trade  with  piece-wages. 

A  union  whose  experience  illustrates  the  difficulty  of  forc- 
ing the  working  of  short-time  where  time-wages  are  paid 
and  the  comparative  ease  of  enforcing  it  among  piece-work- 
ers, is  the  Ladies'  Garment  Workers  of  New  York.  The 
protocol  of  1911  provided  for  an  equal  distribution  of  work 
among  the  entire  working  force,  but  the  union  soon  found 
that,  although  the  manufacturers  retained  all  the  piece 
workers  in  dull  seasons,  many  of  the  employees  who  were 
paid  time-wages  were  being  discharged.  The  employers 
were  reluctant  to  keep  all  of  the  time-workers  since  many 
of  them  were  not  worth  the  standard  rate  of  pay  in  the  dull 
season.  The  Cloth  Hat  and  Cap  Workers'  Union  has  simi- 
larly been  unable  to  enforce  in  shops  paying  time-wages  its 
rule  requiring  an  equal  distribution  of  employment  while 
those  shops  where  piece- wages  are  paid  have  not  objected 
to  the  rule.44  The  secretary  of  the  Lithographers,  also, 
states  that  the  only  reason  that  the  Lithographers  have  been 
unsuccessful  in  their  attempts  to  secure  an  equal  distribu- 
tion of  employment  in  the  slack  seasons  is  that  they  are  paid 
time-wages.45 

It  is  not  to  be  inferred,  however,  that  all  piece- working 
trades  can  enforce  distribution  of  employment.  For  here, 
too,  the  inferiority  of  some  workers  to  others  may  play  a 
prominent  part.  It  is  said  that  the  daily  product  of  glass 
blowers  varies  as  much  as  fifty  per  cent  between  one  work- 
man and  another,  and  as  the  costs  for  heating  a  tank  of 
glass  and  other  incidental  expenses  are  the  same  for  the 
man  who  blows  five  gross  of  bottles  as  for  the  man  who 
blows  ten,  it  is  obvious  that  the  employer  would  prefer  to 
reduce  his  working  force  instead  of  working  short-time. 

44  Interview,  August,  1915. 

45  Interview  with  Secretary  O'Connor,  August,  1915. 


DISTRIBUTION    OF   EMPLOYMENT  127 

2.  In  many  skilled  trades  the  class  of  work  varies  con- 
siderably from  one  shop  to  another  and  an  employee  of  one 
concern  may  be  obliged  to  familiarize  himself  with  the  con- 
ditions peculiar  to  that  establishment.     These  peculiarities 
may  relate  to  the  machinery,  the  process,  the  materials  or 
even  the  patrons  of  the  company.     Through  a  knowledge 
of  these  conditions  many  workmen  are  an  indispensable  part 
of  the  concern.     In  such  cases  the  employer  will  be  more 
likely  to  use  the  method  of  short-time  or  of  rotation  rather 
than  to  dismiss  a  part  of  the  working  force,  because  when 
the  full  force  is  again  required  he  may  not  be  able  to  secure 
the  services  of  the  dismissed  men. 

3.  In  trades  where  an  employer  can  reasonably  expect 
to  recruit  his  working  force  with  but  little  difficulty  or  ex- 
pense, there  is  less  incentive  for  him  to  work  short-time  in 
the  dull  seasons.     This  is  the  case  generally  with  employers 
of  unskilled  and  semi-skilled  workmen.     So  far  as  skilled 
workers  are  concerned  much  depends  upon  the  size  of  the 
industrial   community   and   the   normal   reserve   of   labor. 
When  there  is  more  than  one  establishment  in  a  community, 
there  is  a  greater  probability  that  workmen  can  be  obtained 
when  they  are  needed.     When  a  workman  is  dismissed  from 
the  only  establishment  in  his  community  at  which  he  can 
secure  employment,  he  will  generally  move  to  a  community 
where  his  chances  for  employment  are  greater.     The  pri- 
mary reason  for  short-time  employment  among  the  coal  and 
ore  miners,  textile,  and  lumber  workers,  is  that  the  employ- 
ers are  forced  to  give  to  each  workman  some  employment  to 
induce  him  to  remain  in  the  community,  in  order  that  his 
services  may  be  available  in  the  busy  season.     In  the  large 
industrial  centers   employers  are  not  generally   forced  to 
adopt  this  policy,  because  the  normal  reserve  of  labor  is 
sufficient  to  furnish  the  number  of  workmen  which  will  be 
required  when  he  increases  his  working  force. 

4.  In  some  industries  there  are  important  expenses  which 
are  constant,  regardless  of  the  number  of  workmen  em- 
ployed.    Thus,  charges  for  light,  heat,  power,  superintend- 


128      UNEMPLOYMENT   AND   AMERICAN    TRADE   UNIONS 

ence,  and  subsidiary  labor  may  involve  such  an  expense 
that  it  will  be  more  economical  for  the  manufacturer  to  em- 
ploy the  entire  force  on  short  time,  as  for  example,  every 
other  week,  than  to  work  full  time,  dismissing  the  less  effi- 
cient workmen.  In  other  industries  this  expense  may  be  so 
small  as  to  have  no  influence  upon  the  method  to  be  used. 

Throughout  this  chapter  the  attempt  has  been  made  to 
show  the  position  of  the  unions  in  the  demand  for  an  equal 
distribution  of  employment  in  the  dull  seasons.  Naturally 
stress  has  been  laid  on  the  objections  of  the  employers,  but 
in  the  unions  themselves  there  are  certain  influential  ele- 
ments which  have  steadily  opposed  a  more  equitable  dis- 
tribution of  employment. 

In  the  greater  number  of  local  unions  there  are  certain 
members  comprising  the  more  efficient  workmen,  who 
dominate  the  business  transacted  by  the  union.  Whenever 
the  seasonal  fluctuation  is  of  such  intensity  as  to  cause  the 
dismissal  of  some  of  these  "  regulars,"  the  local  union  is 
insistent  upon  an  equal  division  of  employment.  But  when 
the  fluctuation  results  merely  in  the  discharge  of  a  few 
men  who  are  "  floaters  "  or  young  members,  the  action  of 
the  local  union  is  likely  to  be  different.  In  these  cases  the 
regulars  strenuously  object  to  a  division  of  employment  and 
frequently  refuse  to  abide  by  the  rules  of  the  national  union 
upon  the  subject.  The  Flint  Glass  Workers  at  their  con- 
vention in  1902,  in  the  hope  of  discouraging  such  violations 
of  the  rule  of  equal  division,  directed  one  of  the  local  unions 
to  pay  two  weeks  wages  to  a  member  whom  they  had  not 
allowed  to  share  in  the  division  of  work.46  Such  practices 
still  exist,  however,  for  the  president  in  1915  said:  "Our 
attention  has  been  called  to  the  fact  that  in  certain  localities, 
the  members  of  the  cutting  department  attempt  to  evade 
the  equal  division  of  time  rule  by  catering  to  the  foreman 
of  the  shops  and  receiving  favorite  treatment  from  the 
managers.  Conduct  of  this  kind  is  absolutely  wrong,  and 

46  Proceedings,  1902,  p.  381. 


DISTRIBUTION    OF   EMPLOYMENT  I2Q 

displays  a  weakness  in  trade  union  principles."41  The  mem- 
bers of  the  Typographical  Union  voted  in  1908  to  continue 
the  enforcement  of  the  priority  rules,  which  are  a  great 
hindrance  to  the  equal  distribution  of  employment,  espe- 
cially among  the  substitutes.48 

The  Railroad  Brotherhoods,  Boilermakers,  Iron  Mold- 
ers,  Machinists,  and  other  unions  still  retain  in  their  agree- 
ments provision  for  the  seniority  rights  of  members  in  dull 
periods.  And  even  where  equal  division  is  the  rule,  it  is 
extremely  difficult  of  enforcement  on  account  of  the  hos- 
tility of  the  more  efficient  workmen.  An  official  of  the 
Brewery  Workers  says :  "  This  new  mode  of  laying  off  has 
caused  much  dissatisfaction,  which  certainly  is  not  in  accord 
with  the  socialistic  principles  which  our  organization  pre- 
tends to  advocate,  and  should  not  reveal  itself  so  openly."49 

Despite  these  influences  within  the  unions,  however,  the 
agitation  for  an  equal  distribution  of  employment  in  the  dull 
seasons  is  gaining  great  strength.  Responsibility  for  intro- 
ducing and  promoting  distribution  must  in  great  measure  be 
placed  on  the  unions.  In  only  one  of  the  fourteen  indus- 
tries represented  by  unions  whose  members  work  on  short- 
time  and  in  rotation  during  dull  seasons,  is  it  likely  that 
these  methods  of  meeting  the  contraction  of  demand  would 
have  been  instituted  and  maintained  without  the  influence 
of  the  unions.  Conclusive  evidence  of  this  is  found  in  the 
fact  that  the  majority  of  non-union  establishments  in  these 
thirteen  trades  dismiss  a  part  of  their  working  forces  in  the 
slack  seasons  instead  of  working  on  short-time  or  in  ro- 
tation. 

4T  Circular  of  the  Flint  Glass  Workers'  Union,  Number  13,  Feb- 
ruary 20,  1915,  p.  i. 

48  Typographical  Journal,  vol.  32,  p.  645. 

49  Proceedings,  1903,  p.  199. 


CHAPTER  VI 
UNEMPLOYMENT  INSURANCE 

The  development  of  beneficiary  features  in  American 
trade  unions  has  been  far  slower  than  in  the  European  trade 
unions.  Of  the  in  national  unions  affiliated  with  the 
American  Federation  of  Labor  in  1916  only  69  were  re- 
ported as  paying  benefits  of  any  kind,  and  of  these  35  had 
established  only  one  form  of  benefit.  Only  9  unions  re- 
ported that  they  had  expended  anything  for  the  support  of 
their  unemployed.  The  expenditures  for  beneficiary  fea- 
tures of  these  69  unions  were  $3,545,823  for  the  year  1916, 
and  of  this  sum  only  $120,770  or  about  three  per  cent  was 
for  the  relief  of  the  unemployed.1 

In  1908,  669  of  the  1058  trade  unions  in  Great  Britain 
paid  some  form  of  unemployment  benefit.  The  total  ex- 
penditures in  1908  in  England  for  this  benefit  alone  was 
$6,289,565  or  $2.75  per  capita.  This  comparison  shows 
the  relatively  small  importance  which  American  trade 
unions  attach  to  organized  out-of-work  relief..  In  the  100 
principal  trade  unions  of  England,  which  represent  about 
60  per  cent  of  the  total  membership,  the  total  amount  of 
unemployment  benefits  paid  during  the  three  years  1908- 
1910  was  $13,250,000,  which  was  31  per  cent  of  all  expen- 
ditures.2 

There  are  only  three  American  national  unions  which  at 
this  time,  1916,  are  paying  out-of-work  benefits — the  Cigar 
Makers,  the  Deutsch-Amerikanischen  Typographia,  and  the 
Diamond  Workers.8 

1  Report  of  Secretary,  in  Proceedings  of  the  Thirty-sixth  Annual 
Convention  of  the  American  Federation  of  Labor,  1916,  p.  31. 

2  The  I7th  Report  on  Trade  Unions  of  Great  Britain.    Report  en 
Trade  Unions  in  1908-1910,  pp.  iii,  xxi,  xxxiii. 

3  Both  the  Coal  Hoisting  Engineers,  which  disbanded  in  1904,  and 
the  Jewelry  Workers,  which  disbanded  in   1912,  paid  out-of-work 

130 


UNEMPLOYMENT   INSURANCE  13! 

For  many  years  prior  to  the  adoption  of  this  form  of 
benefit  by  the  Cigar  Makers,  several  of  the  local  unions  of 
cigar  makers  had  formed  systems  of  their  own.  As  early 
as  1875  the  New  York  branch  provided  that  members  who 
had  been  unemployed  for  two  weeks  were  entitled  to  receive 
benefits  for  a  term  of  three  weeks.*  At  the  convention  in 
1876  Mr.  Samuel  Gompers,  then  secretary  of  the  New  York 
City  local  union,  proposed  a  national  out-of-work  benefit 
modeled  upon  the  New  York  system,  but  the  proposed 
benefit  received  scant  attention.5  During  the  following 
years  several  other  local  unions  adopted  the  New  York  plan 
and  the  movement  for  a  national  out-of-work  benefit  found 
many  adherents.6  President  Hurst  recommended  to  several 
conventions  that  the  local  unions  be  allowed  to  vote  upon  the 
question  but  the  opponents  of  the  plan  declared  that  the 
higher  dues  necessitated  by  the  proposed  benefit  would  force 
many  members  from  the  union,  and  defeated  the  measure.7 
President  Strasser  and  other  officials  argued  in  favor  of  an 
out-of-work  benefit  at  every  convention,  but  it  was  not  until 
the  eighteenth  convention,  held  in  September,  1889,  that 
the  benefit  system  as  framed  by  Mr.  Gompers  was  adopted.8 

The  system  which  went  into  effect  in  January,  1890,  pro- 
vided that  unemployed  members  who  had  paid  dues  for  one 
year  were  entitled  to  $3.00  per  week  and  50  cents  for  each 
additional  day,  the  benefit  beginning  with  the  second  week 
of  unemployment.  After  receiving  benefits  for  six  consecu- 
tive weeks  the  member  was  not  entitled  to  any  benefit  for 
seven  weeks  thereafter,  and  the  maximum  amount  to  be 
received  in  one  year  was  $72.00.  No  benefit  was  to  be 
paid  from  December  16  to  January  15  and  from  July  I  to 
July  15,  as  manufacturers  generally  closed  their  shops  dur- 

benefits.  The  British  trade  unions  which  have  members  in  the 
United  States — the  Amalgamated  Carpenters  and  the  Amalgamated 
Engineers — provide  for  unemployment  insurance. 

*  Cigar  Makers'  Journal,  February,  1889,  p.  8. 

8  Ibid.,  September,  1876,  p.  i. 

6  Ibid.,  April,  1877,  P-  x- 

7  Ibid.,  April,  1879,  p.  4. 

8  Proceedings  of  the  Eighteenth  Convention,  1889,  p.  18. 


132       UNEMPLOYMENT   AND   AMERICAN   TRADE   UNIONS 

ing  these  periods.  If  a  member  was  thrown  out  of  employ- 
ment on  account  of  intoxication,  disorderly  conduct,  or  bad 
workmanship  he  was  not  entitled  to  any  benefit  for  eight 
weeks,  but  inability  to  hold  a  job  did  not  deprive  a  member 
of  his  benefit.  Those  receiving  benefits  were  required  to 
report  daily  at  the  secretary's  office  and  sign  their  names  in 
a  book  provided  for  that  purpose.  Members  were  not  en- 
titled to  the  benefit  if  they  refused  to  work  in  a  shop  where 
work  was  offered,  or  neglected  to  apply  for  employment  in 
a  shop  if  directed  to  do  so  by  an  officer  of  the  local  union. 

The  system  was  successful  from  the  beginning,  although 
many  attempts  were  made  to  break  down  the  safeguards 
established  for  its  proper  management.  At  the  convention 
in  1891  it  was  provided  that  a  member  must  procure  from 
the  collector  of  the  shop  in  which  he  was  last  employed  a 
certificate  stating  the  cause  of  his  discharge,  and  that  if  any 
member  failed  to  register  for  three  successive  days  the 
benefit  of  previous  registration  was  forfeited,  if  such  regis- 
tration was  for  less  than  one  week.9  On  account  of  the  great 
increase  of  out-of-work  benefits  paid  in  1894,  1895,  an<^ 
1896,  the  convention  in  the  latter  year  voted  to  reduce  the 
expenditures  for  this  benefit.  This  was  done  by  restricting 
the  benefit  to  cigar  makers  of  two  years'  membership,  by 
reducing  the  maximum  amount  to  be  drawn  in  one  year 
from  $72.00  to  $54.00,  and  by  extending  the  periods  during 
which  the  benefit  was  not  to  be  paid.10  The  system  has  re- 
mained unchanged  since  the  convention  of  1896. 

During  the  first  year  of  its  operation  $22,760  was  paid  to 
2286  members,  or  less  than  10  per  cent  of  the  membership. 
The  per  capita  cost  for  the  first  year  was  92  cents,  87  cents 
for  the  second  year,  and  65  cents  for  the  third  year.  Dur- 
ing the  depression  of  1893-1896  the  cost  increased  greatly, 
there  being  expended  in  1896  $175,767  or  $6.43  per  capita. 
Since  then  the  cost  has  gradually  diminished,  and  except  for 
the  years  1908,  1909,  1912,  and  1914,  has  never  exceeded 

9  Proceedings  of  the  Nineteenth  Convention,  1891,  p.  23. 

10  Proceedings  of  the  Twenty-first  Convention,  18915,  p.  31. 


UNEMPLOYMENT  INSURANCE  133 

$1.00  per  capita.  The  system  had  been  in  operation  twenty- 
five  years  on  January  I,  1915,  and  had  cost  the  union  $i,- 
486,732,  or  an  average  annual  per  capita  cost  of  about  $1.90. 

The  Deutsch-Amerikanischen  Typographia  established  its 
out-of-work  benefit  in  1884,  eleven  years  after  the  national 
union  was  founded.  As  was  the  case  with  the  Cigar 
Makers,  the  system  was  modeled  after  a  benefit  in  opera- 
tion in  one  of  the  local  unions.  The  only  changes  which 
have  been  made  in  the  original  plan  have  had  to  do  with  the 
amount  of  the  weekly  benefit.  At  the  outset  the  benefit  was 
fixed  at  $5.00  per  week,  but  as  it  was  found  that  the  assess- 
ments more  than  paid  for  the  system,  it  was  increased  in 
1888  to  $6.00  per  week.  However,  in  1894  the  weekly 
benefit  was  reduced  to  the  original  amount  on  account  of 
increased  payments  due  to  the  general  business  depression 
and  to  the  introduction  of  the  linotype..  In  1908,  owing  to 
the  prosperous  financial  condition  of  the  union,  it  was  again 
raised  to  $6.00  per  week  where  it  has  since  remained. 

The  operation  of  the  system  at  present  is  in  many  respects 
similar  to  that  of  the  Cigar  Makers.  Unemployed  members 
who  have  been  in  good  standing  for  two  years  are  entitled 
to  $6.00  per  week,  beginning  with  the  fourth  week  of  un- 
employment. After  having  received  benefits  for  four  weeks, 
a  period  of  three  weeks  must  intervene  before  the  member 
is  again  entitled  to  the  benefit,  and  the  amount  received 
during  the  fiscal  year  cannot  exceed  $96.00  Members  who 
are  unemployed  through  their  own  fault  are  not  entitled  to 
the  benefit  until  they  have  been  on  the  unemployed  list  for 
seven  weeks,  but  if  the  situation  has  been  voluntarily  given 
up,  the  member  is  allowed  to  draw  the  benefit  after  a  period 
of  four  weeks.  The  secretaries  of  the  local  unions  specify 
certain  hours  of  the  day  during  which  the  unemployed  must 
register  at  the  union  offices.  Should  the  member  receive 
employment  for  one  day  while  on  the  unemployed  list,  $i  is 
deducted  from  his  weekly  benefit,  but  four  days'  employment 
in  one  week  debars  him  from  any  benefit  for  that  week. 
Members  who  refuse  to  accept  a  situation  are  not  allowed  to 


134 


UNEMPLOYMENT   AND   AMERICAN   TRADE   UNIONS 


register  for  a  period  of  six  weeks,  while  refusal  to  work  as 
a  substitute  debars  from  the  benefit  for  two  weeks.  In- 
ability to  hold  a  position  debars  a  member  from  any  benefit, 
and  only  through  the  action  of  the  local  union  can  he  be 
given  any  financial  assistance. 

The  cost  of  the  out-of-work  benefit  in  the  Cigar  Makers' 
Union  and  in  the  Typographia  is  shown  in  the  following 
table : 

COST  OF  MAINTAINING  THE  OUT-OF-WORK  BENEFIT 


Typographia 

Cigar  Makers 

Year 

Total  Cost 

Per  Capita 
Cost 

Total  Cost 

Per  Capita 
Cost 

1885 

$    I,Il8.9O 

$   2.00 

1886 

1,453-08 

1-52 

1887 

I,24O.IO 

I  15 

1888 

1,315.13 

1.16 

1889 

6,281.50 

5-55 

1890 

4,315-00 

3-47 

$  22,760.50 

$    .92 

1891 

6,067.00 

4-58 

21,223.50 

.87 

1892 

9,359-50 

6-77 

17,460.75 

•65 

1893 

7,835-00 

5-67 

89,402.75 

3-34 

1894 

17,262.50 

14-33 

174,517.25 

6.27 

1895 

9,464.20 

8.66 

166,377.25 

5-99 

1896 

7,8l2.OO 

7.00 

175,767.25 

6-43 

1897 

8,485.00 

7-83 

117,471.40 

4.46 

1898 

8,603.00 

7.82 

70,197.70 

2.65 

1899 

11,135.00 

10.39 

38,037.00 

1.31 

I90O 

8,703.00 

8-33 

23,897.00 

.70 

I9OI 

6,716.00 

6.56 

27,083.76 

•79 

I9O2 

7,839.00 

7.86 

2I,07I.OO 

-56 

1903 

4,846.00 

4.86 

15,558.00 

•39 

1904 

5,785.00 

5-82 

29,872.50 

•72 

1905 

5,105.00 

5-23 

35,168.50 

.87 

1906 

5,086.OO 

5-22 

23,911.00 

.61 

1907 

3,8O2.OO 

3.84 

19,497.50 

-47 

1908 

6,585.00 

6.78 

101,483.50 

2-51 

1909 

6,350.00 

6.69 

76,107.25 

1.71 

I9IO 

4.OII.OO 

4-34 

39,917.00 

•91 

I9II 

3,40I.OO 

3-70 

36,942.50 

.88 

1912 

3,670.00 

4-13 

42,911.05 

1.  06 

1913 

3,248.00 

3-64 

31,898.71 

•79 

1914 

3,l88.OO 

3-59 

68,198.00 

1.70 

Total  

$l8o,o8l,9I 

$1,486,732.62 

Average  .... 

6,002.73 

5-6i 

59,469.30 

1.90 

UNEMPLOYMENT   INSURANCE  135 

Some  comparison  can  be  made  of  the  cost  of  the  out-of- 
work  benefit  in  the  two  unions.  During  the  twenty  years 
existence  of  the  Cigar  Makers'  system  the  average  annual 
per  capita  cost  has  been  $1.90,  while  the  average  annual  per 
capita  cost  of  the  German  Printers  has  been  $5.61.  But 
this  great  difference  has  not  been  due  chiefly  to  a  greater 
amount  of  unemployment,  although  the  printers  are  more 
subject  to  unemployment  than  the  cigar  makers.  The 
weekly  benefit  of  the  Cigar  Makers  is  only  one-half  of  that 
of  the  Typographia,  while  the  maximum  yearly  benefit  is 
only  about  sixty  per  cent  as  great. 

During  the  past  few  years  there  appears  to  have  been  a 
tendency  towards  decreased  per  capita  costs  in  both  unions. 
This  is  partly  due  in  the  case  of  the  Cigar  Makers  to  a  more 
stringent  administration  of  the  system,  while  in  the  Typo- 
graphia it  is  the  result  of  the  introduction  of  the  old  age 
pension  in  July,  1908.  Secretary  Miller  of  the  Typographia 
says  that  the  majority  of  the  members  receiving  the  benefit 
for  the  unemployed  are  the  older  men  who  are  unable  to 
operate  typesetting  machines,  and  that  before  the  introduc- 
tion of  the  old  age  pension  these  members  drew  the  maxi- 
mum out-of-work  benefit  each  year.11 

As  the  periods  in  which  the  two  unions  have  paid  unem- 
ployment benefits  are  about  the  same,  it  is  not  surprising 
that  there  is  a  striking  correspondence  between  the  fluctua- 
tions in  their  per  capita  costs.  Both  fall  and  rise  together 
throughout  the  twenty-five  years.  From  1892  to  1894  the 
Cigar  Makers'  per  capita  cost  rose  from  65  cents  to  $6.27 
and  the  Typographia's  from  $6.77  to  $14.33,  while  from 
1899  to  1907  the  cost  of  the  Cigar  Makers  decreased  gradu- 
ally from  $1.31  to  47  cents  and  that  of  the  Typographia  from 
$10.39  to  $3-84.  Both  rose  during  the  panic  of  1907-1908 
and  have  since  decreased  gradually. 

The  Diamond  Workers'  Union,  organized  in  1902,  estab- 
lished an  out-of-work  benefit  in  1912.  The  system  went 
into  effect  on  August  I,  1912.  It  provided  that  the  out- 

11  In  letter  to  the  writer,  October  19,  1915. 


136       UNEMPLOYMENT   AND   AMERICAN    TRADE   UNIONS 

of-work  fund  should  be  maintained  by  assessments  of  ten 
cents  per  week  upon  all  employed  members.  Those  mem- 
bers who  had  been  employed  for  thirteen  full  weeks  during 
the  first  half-year  of  their  membership  and  who  had  be«n 
unemployed  for  six  consecutive  weeks  were  entitled  to 
benefits.  The  unemployed  were  to  receive  a  benefit  of  $6.00 
per  week  and  $1.00  for  each  additional  day  of  idleness,  but 
could  not  draw  benefits  for  more  than  thirteen  weeks,  or 
seventy-eight  working  days,  during  the  fiscal  year.  Mem- 
bers drawing  benefits  who  found  employment  for  four  con- 
secutive weeks  or  more  were  net  entitled  to  an  additional 
benefit  until  they  had  been  idle  for  six  additional  consecu- 
tive weeks,  while  those  who  had  been  drawing  the  benefit 
and  received  work  for  less  than  four  weeks  were  not  to 
receive  the  benefit  until  they  had  been  idle  for  as  many  days 
as  they  had  been  employed.  Members  who  had  resigned 
from  their  employment  without  reasons  satisfactory  to  the 
executive  board  or  who  had  courted  their  discharge  were 
excluded  from  the  benefit,  and  those  who  refused  to  accept 
employment  when  offered  forfeited  all  rights  to  the  benefit 
during  the  fiscal  year.  Those  receiving  the  benefit  were 
compelled  to  report  at  the  headquarters  of  the  union  every 
Tuesday  and  Friday  between  the  hours  of  10  and  12  A.M.12 
Several  important  changes  in  the  system  have  been  made 
since  its  establishment.  In  July,  1913,  the  weekly  benefit 
was  increased  from  $6.00  to  $7.50,  and  members  became 
entitled  to  the  benefit  after  they  had  been  unemployed  for 
four  weeks  instead  of  six  weeks.13  At  first  it  was  thought 
that  with  an  initial  donation  of  $600.00  to  the  fund  from  the 
general  funds  of  the  union  the  assessment  of  ten  cents  per 
week  would  be  sufficient  to  defray  the  expenses  of  the 
benefit  system.  It  appears  that  in  normal  times  the  income 
from  this  source  was  sufficient  to  cover  the  expenses,  but 
during  the  depression  of  1914-1915  the  expenditures  for  the 

12  Circular  of  the  Diamond  Workers  Protective  Union  of  Amer- 
ica (New  York,  n.  d.). 

18  Letter  to  the  writer  from  President  Andries  Meyer,  March  7, 
1916. 


UNEMPLOYMENT   INSURANCE  137 

benefit  were  so  large  that  it  was  necessary  to  transfer  large 
sums  from  the  general  fund  of  the  union  to  the  out-of-work 
fund.  Thus,  from  January  I,  1914,  to  March  31,  1915, 
$22,600  was  drawn  from  the  general  fund  for  the  use  of  the 
out-of-work  benefit.14  In  1916  the  employed  members  were 
assessed  $1.00  per  week  besides  the  regular  dues  in  order 
to  provide  new  resources  for  the  out-of-work  fund.15 

The  following  table  shows  the  amounts  paid  since  Oc- 
tober i,  1912: 

OUT-OF-WORK   BENEFITS    PAID  BY  THE   DIAMOND   WORKERS'   PRO- 
TECTIVE UNION 

Quarter  Ending  Amount 

December  31,  1912 $     435-OO 

March  31,  1913 78.00 

June  30,  1913 36.00 

September  30,  1913  181,25 

December  31,  1913 567.50 

March  31,  1914 % . .      3,041.25 

June  30,  1914  4,863.75 

September  30,  1914 7,163.75 

December  31,  1914 7,213-75 

March  31,  1915 2,622.50 

June  30,  1915  96.25 

September  30,  1915    670.00 

December  31,  1915 258.70 

Total  cost $27,227.70 

Average  per  capita  $       86.43 

Although  but  three  national  unions  have  established  out- 
of-work  benefits,  a  great  many,  at  one  time  or  another,  have 
made  special  provision  for  the  unemployed  by  donating 
money  for  this  purpose  from  the  general  funds  of  the  union. 
These  emergency  benefits  have  usually  been  put  into  opera- 
tion during  periods  of  general  business  depression. 

The  following  table  shows  the  total  annual  amounts  in- 
cluding regular  benefits  and  special  appropriations,  which 
have  been  appropriated  for  the  relief  of  the  unemployed  by 
the  unions  reporting  to  the  American  Federation  of  Labor. 

14  Quarterly  Financial  Statements,  Jan.  i,  to  Mar.  31,  1914;  Jan.  i 
to  Mar.  31,  1915. 

16  Letter  to  the  writer  from  President  Andries  Meyer,  March  7, 
1916. 


138      UNEMPLOYMENT   AND   AMERICAN    TRADE    UNIONS 


UNEMPLOYMENT  BENEFITS  PAID  BY  UNIONS  REPORTING  TO  THE 
AMERICAN  FEDERATION  OF  LABOR,  1903-1916 


Year 

Amount 

Year 

Amount 

1903 
1904 

1905 
1906 
1907 
1908 

$  79,538.3? 
78,073.25 
85,050.72 
79,582.70 
46,481.79 
205,254.31 

I9II 
1912 

1913 
1914 

1915 
I9l6 

$218,742.71 
215,398.60 
69,445.70 
99,024.88 
256,002.29 
I2O,77O.6o 

IQOQ 

484,028.49 

Total  

$2,235,202.41 

IQIO 

I97,8o8.OO 

Average  

$159,657.32 

Typical  examples  of  emergency  funds  for  the  unem- 
ployed are  those  of  the  Flint  Glass  Workers  and  the  Glass 
Bottle  Blowers.  The  general  business  depression  of  1907 
closed  many  factories  in  which  members  of  the  Flint  Glass 
Workers  were  employed  and  the  national  union  was  be- 
sieged with  appeals  from  the  unemployed  who  numbered 
over  thirty  per  cent  of  the  membership.  A  relief  fund  was 
established  and  about  $5,000  was  donated  monthly  to  the 
unemployed  until  business  conditions  improved.16 

During  the  same  depression  the  Glass  Bottle  Blowers  were 
confronted  with  a  situation  not  unlike  that  of  the  Flint  Glass 
Workers.  The  general  office  received  so  many  applications 
for  help  that  the  executive  board,  on  January  7,  1909,  de- 
cided to  establish  a  fund  for  the  relief  of  the  unemployed 
by  increasing  the  assessment  upon  the  earnings  of  those  em- 
ployed. Within  a  few  weeks  after  its  establishment  3200 
of  the  8200  members  were  receiving  relief.  The  unemployed 
married  members  were  given  $7.00  per  week  and  the  unem- 
ployed single  members,  $5.00  per  week  for  an  indefinite 
period.  During  the  period  in  which  relief  was  granted  there 
was  expended  $2<5o,5O2.75.17  During  the  depression  of 
1914-1915  the  national  union  loaned  money  to  the  local 
unions  to  relieve  the  unemployed.  In  1914  the  sum  of  $Q,- 
890.13  was  expended,18  while  in  1915  the  expenditure 

10  Proceedings,  1908,  p.  91  et  seq. 

Proceedings,  1910,  pp.  50,  70. 
18  Proceedings  of  American  Federation  of  Labor,  1914,  p.  29, 


UNEMPLOYMENT   INSURANCE  139 

amounted  to  $55,ooo.19  Although  this  money  was  to  be 
repaid,  it  is  said  that  there  is  very  little  likelihood  that  this 
will  be  done. 

Although  the  out-of-work  benefit  has  been  utilized  so 
little  by  the  American  trade  unions,  there  is  scarcely  a  union 
in  which  there  has  not  been  a  more  or  less  continuous  agita- 
tion for  its  adoption.  These  campaigns  have  been  waged 
not  only  in  the  unions  which  were  in  existence  when  the 
Cigar  Makers  and  the  Typographia  adopted  the  benefit,  but 
also  in  unions  founded  within  the  last  fifteen  years.  The 
agitation  has  been  greatest  during  periods  of  general  busi- 
ness depression,  but  it  goes  on  even  in  the  most  prosperous 
years. 

The  Brotherhood  of  Carpenters  and  Joiners  affords  an 
illustration  of  this  continuous  agitation.  P.  J.  McGuire, 
the  founder  of  the  union,  advocated  the.  establishment  of 
an  unemployed  benefit.  In  the  conventions  of  1894  and  1896 
he  expounded  its  advantages  and  recommended  its  adoption, 
but  each  time  the  proposed  benefit  was  defeated.20  Presi- 
dent Lloyd  at  the  New  York  convention  of  1898  urged  the 
delegates  to  establish  a  benefit  for  the  unemployed,  and 
this  time  the  question  was  submitted  to  a  referendum  vote 
but  was  defeated.21  During  the  panic  of  1908  Secretary 
Duffy  reported  to  the  convention  that  he  heartily  favored 
some  plan  whereby  the  union  might  be  able  to  give  aid  to 
the  unemployed.22  At  almost  every  convention  since,  the 
question  has  been  debated  and  in  many  of  the  issues  of 
The  Carpenter  there  are  letters  from  members  urging  the 
union  to  adopt  some  form  of  unemployment  insurance. 

The  Typographical  Union,  which  has  an  extensive  benefit 
system,  has  frequently  considered  the  advisability  of  estab- 
lishing an  out-of-work  benefit.  Its  officers,  like  those  of 
the  Carpenters,  have  been  the  most  aggressive  exponents  of 
the  advantages  to  be  derived  from  such  action.  President 

19  Proceedings  of  American  Federation  of  Labor,  1915,  p.  30. 

20  The  Carpenter,  January,  1908,  p.  10. 

21  Proceedings,  1898,  p.  8. 

22  Proceedings,  1908,  p.  5. 


I4O       UNEMPLOYMENT   AND   AMERICAN    TRADE   UNIONS 

Prescott  at  the  convention  of  1894  urged  the  members  to 
adopt  the  out-of-work  benefit  instead  of  the  sick  benefit.23 
During  the  period  in  which  the  linotype  was  displacing  great 
numbers  of  printers  the  agitation  for  an  out-of-work  benefit 
became  general  throughout  the  union,  but  each  time  it  was 
put  to  a  vote  of  the  membership  it  was  defeated.  As  late 
as  1907  President  Lynch  said :  "  It  has  long  been  the  belief 
of  the  president  that  the  Typographical  Union  is  great 
enough,  experienced  enough,  and  in  the  possession  of  the 
necessary  machinery,  to  establish  and  successfully  carry  on 
an  out-of-work  benefit."24  During  the  depression  of  1914 
many  letters  were  written  to  the  Typographical  Journal 
urging  the  adoption  of  this  benefit,  and  the  convention  of 
1915  provided  for  the  appointment  of  a  committee  to  inves- 
tigate the  feasibility  of  establishing  an  out-of-work  benefit 
for  the  International  Union.25 

When  the  Plumbers  in  1899  decided  to  inaugurate  a  sys- 
tem of  benefits,  a  campaign  was  made  for  the  out-of-work 
benefit,  but  through  the  conservatism  of  its  officers  other 
benefits  were  chosen  instead.  In  1908  the  executive  board 
was  authorized  by  the  convention  to  ascertain  the  probable 
cost  of  the  benefit,  but  the  finances  of  the  union  were  in 
such  condition  that  the  adoption  of  the  benefit  at  that  time 
would  have  been  impossible.26  In  the  Pattern  Makers  this 
benefit  was  considered  at  the  organization  of  the  union,  and 
has  since  been  discussed  at  nearly  every  convention.  As 
several  of  its  local  unions  already  had  unemployment  bene- 
fits, the  movement  made  considerable  headway,  but  each 
time  the  question  has  been  submitted  to  the  members,  it  has 
failed  of  adoption.  During  the  financial  panic  of  1896  and 
the  years  of  depression  following  there  was  a  strong  move- 
ment in  favor  of  the  out-of-work  benefit  in  the  Iron,  Steel 
and  Tin  Workers,  Painters,  Granite  Cutters,  Bakers,  and 
Lithographers,  but  in  recent  years  there  appears  to  have 

23  Barnett,  The  Printers,  p.  103. 
2*  Ibid.,  p.  106. 

Proceedings,  1915,  p.  65. 
2fl  Proceedings,  1908,  p.  93. 


UNEMPLOYMENT   INSURANCE  14! 

been  no  attempt  in  these  unions  to  reopen  the  question.  On 
the  other  hand,  in  the  Brewery  Workers,  Metal  Polishers, 
Photo-Engravers,  Boot  and  Shoe  Workers,  and  Potters,  the 
out-of-work  benefit  has  been  the  subject  of  consideration 
during  the  past  few  years,  and  at  each  succeeding  conven- 
tion seems  to  gain  additional  support. 

The  failure  of  the  national  unions  to  provide  out-of-work 
benefits  has  led  many  local  unions  in  various  trades  to  estab- 
lish systems  of  their  own.  These  exist  in  nearly  all  unions 
and  some  of  them  have  been  in  existence  for  many  years. 
Probably  the  oldest  and  most  important  are  those  found 
among  the  Printers. 

The  Typographical  Association  of  New  York  City,  as 
early  as  1831,  provided  that  the  sum  of  $3.00  per  week 
should  be  paid  to  unemployed  single  members  and  $4.00 
per  week  to  unemployed  married  members.  This  benefit 
was  to  be  paid  as  long  as  the  members  were  unemployed 
unless  a  member  refused  to  accept  a  situation  offered  him 
or  made  no  effort  to  procure  employment.  This  system 
remained  in  operation  for  only  a  few  years,  but  it  was  re- 
established later  and  was  maintained  throughout  a  business 
depression.27  In  September,  1893,  the  unemployed  benefit 
was  reestablished,  but  it  was  not  until  March,  1896,  that  a 
permanent  system  was  founded.  The  money  for  this  bene- 
fit was  to  be  secured  by  an  assessment  of  one  per  cent  on 
the  earnings  of  those  employed.  Unemployed  members 
who  had  been  in  good  standing  for  one  year  were  entitled 
to  a  benefit  of  $4.00  per  week  for  the  first  four  weeks  of 
unemployment,  but  not  more  than  four  weeks'  benefit  could 
be  drawn  in  any  six  weeks  nor  more  than  $60.00  in  any 
one  year.28  This  system  remained  in  operation  until  Au- 
gust, 1907,  during  which  time  the  sum  of  $520,645  was  ex- 
pended. The  following  table  shows  the  annual  total  cost 
and  the  annual  average  per  capita  cost. 

2T  George  A.  Stevens,  "The  History  of  Typographical  Union 
Number  Six  "  in  Annual  Report  of  the  New  York  Bureau  of  Labor 
Statistics,  1911,  part  i,  pp.  112  and  113. 

28  Ibid.,  pp.  478  and  479. 


142 


UNEMPLOYMENT   AND   AMERICAN    TRADE   UNIONS 


COST  OF  MAINTAINING  THE  OUT-OF-WORK  BENEFIT  IN  THE  NEW 
YORK  CITY  TYPOGRAPHICAL  UNION 


Year 

Total  Cost 

Per  Capita 
Cost 

Year 

Total  Cost 

I 

Per  Capita 
Cost 

1894 

1895 
1896 
1897 
1898 
1899 

I9OO 
I9OI 

$18,259.04 

17,779.05 
25,365.20 
30,211.70 
35,169.24 
37,274-13 

40,323.65 
40,451.46 

$3-59 
3.8i 
5.38 
6.29 
6.90 
6.88 

7-45 
7.36 

I9O2 
1903 
1904 

1905 
1906 
1907 

$40,7I5.75 
44,510.86 
45,458.12 
50,385.80 
54,701.69 
!     40,039-56 

$7.07 
7.14 
7.O6 
7.40 

8.II 
5-95 

Total  .  .  . 

.  $520,645.25 

Average  . 

•  ;  $37,188.90 

$6.45 

It  will  be  noticed  that  the  per  capita  cost  shows  no  sudden 
changes  in  periods  of  depression  or  prosperity.  With  but 
few  exceptions,  the  cost  increased  each  year — from  $3.59  in 
1894  to  $8.11  in  1906.  Inasmuch  as  the  weekly  benefit  and 
the  maximum  amount  which  could  be  drawn  in  one  year 
remained  the  same  it  is  evident  that  the  benefit,  if  continued, 
would  have  become  a  serious  financial  drain  upon  the  union's 
resources.  Since  August,  1907,  when  the  system  was  abol- 
ished, the  unemployed  who  have  been  in  need  of  assistance 
have  been  given  benefits,  ranging  from  $5.00  to  $15.0x5  ac- 
cording to  individual  need,  through  a  benefit  board  which 
investigates  each  case  to  prevent  imposition.  The  money 
for  this  relief  has  been  secured  by  a  special  assessment  of 
one  half  of  one  per  cent  on  the  earnings  of  those  employed. 
During  the  depression  of  1914  this  source  of  income  was 
insufficient  and  an  assessment  of  five  per  cent  on  all  earn- 
ings of  over  $10.00  per  week  was  made.29  Several  other 
local  unions  of  the  Printers,  especially  the  Chicago  union, 
have  been  paying  out-of-work  benefits  for  several  years.30 

Notwithstanding  the  fact  that  their  national  union  pays 
unemployment  benefits  the  three  hundred  German  type- 
setters of  the  New  York  City  local  union  have  established 
an  additional  benefit.  This  is  so  arranged  that  after  a 
member  has  received  the  national  benefit  for  four  weeks 


The  Survey,  February  20,  1915,  p.  550. 
30  Typographical  Journal,  January,  1915,  p.  42. 


UNEMPLOYMENT   INSURANCE  143 

the  local  union  provides  a  benefit  for  the  succeeding  weeks, 
during  which  the  unemployed  member  receives  no  benefit 
from  the  national  union.81 

The  Boot  and  Shoe  Workers82  and  the  Lithographers83 
have  constitutional  provisions  recommending  that  their 
local  unions  establish  out-of-work  benefit  funds.  In  both 
unions  several  of  the  subordinate  unions  have  acted  upon 
the  suggestion.  The  New  York  City  branch  of  the  Lithog- 
raphers, for  instance,  provides  that  members  who  have  been 
unemployed  for  one  week  are  entitled  to  a  benefit  of  $3.00 
per  week.  The  maximum  amount  that  can  be  secured  in 
one  year  is  $60.  To  be  entitled  to  the  benefit,  a  member 
must  secure  from  the  delegate  of  the  shop  in  which  he  was 
last  employed  a  certificate  stating  the  cause  of  his  discharge 
or  lay-off.  If  he  is  instructed  by  a  local  union  officer  to 
apply  for  a  position  and  fails  to  do  so,  he  is  not  entitled  to 
any  benefit.34 

The  Bakery  and  Confectionery  Workers  at  its  convention 
in  1904  recommended  that  "immediate  steps  be  taken  to 
create  in  every  local  union  an  out-of-work  benefit."85  In 
1915  Secretary  Iffland  stated  that  about  thirty  or  forty  local 
unions  had  inaugurated  systems  for  the  support  of  their 
unemployed.86  In  the  Brewery  Workers  there  are  prob- 
ably not  less  than  twenty  local  unions  which  pay  out-of- 
work  benefits,  but  as  no  report  of  these  funds  is  made 
to  the  national  union,  detailed  information  cannot  be  secured 
concerning  them.37  The  Newark,  New  Jersey,  local  union, 
with  370  members,  reported  to  the  convention  of  1903  that 
it  had  expended  $10,000  during  the  previous  year  for  the 
support  of  its  unemployed,38  and  the  Chicago  local  union  of 
650  members  reported  that  in  1900  it  had  disbursed  $3,652 

31  The  Survey,  February  20,  1915,  p.  549. 

32  Constitution,  1913,  sec.  64. 

38  Constitution,  1913,  art.  4,  sec.  5. 
3*  Constitution,  1905,  art.  3,  sees.  2,  3,  4  and  5. 
35  Bakers'  Journal,  October  21,  1905,  p.  i. 
8(5  Interview,  August,  1915. 

37  Interview  with  Secretary  Proebstle,  August,  1915. 

38  Proceedings,  1903,  p.  193. 


144       UNEMPLOYMENT   AND   AMERICAN    TRADE   UNIONS 

on  account  of  its  unemployment  benefit.39  The  Cleveland 
branch  provides  that  a  member  who  has  been  out  of  employ- 
ment for  four  weeks  is  entitled  to  a  benefit  of  $3.00  per 
week  for  ten  weeks  during  a  year,40  and  the  New  York 
City  local  union  with  1200  members  pays  a  benefit  of  $4.00 
per  week  for  twelve  weeks  in  each  of  two  years,  after  which 
a  member  must  pay  dues  for  a  full  year  before  he  will  again 
be  entitled  to  the  benefit.41 

Several  of  the  larger  local  unions  of  the  Pattern  Makers 
have  had  out-of-work  benefit  systems  in  operation  for  the 
past  ten  years.  The  Boston  association  established  its 
benefit  in  1906.  It  was  provided  that  a  member  who  had 
been  in  good  standing  for  at  least  six  months  should  be 
entitled  to  a  benefit  of  $7.00  per  week,  such  benefit  to  begin 
after  the  first  week  of  unemployment  and  to  be  limited  to 
thirteen  weeks  in  any  one  year.42  During  the  period  April, 
!9i3>  to  April,  1914,  $4,280  was  expended  for  this  benefit.43 
The  New  York  City  local  union  has  paid  the  sum  of  $5.00 
per  week  as  relief  to  its  unemployed  members  for  several 
years.  During  the  year  1908  this  benefit  cost  the  union  an 
average  of  $728  each  week.44 

Among  the  Photo-Engravers,  the  local  unions  in  Phila- 
delphia, New  York,  Chicago,  and  several  other  cities  have 
successful  out-of-work  funds.  The  New  York  local  union 
pays  to  the  unemployed  a  weekly  benefit  of  $6.00  for  an 
indefinite  period.45 

In  the  following  unions  there  exist  but  one  or  two  local- 
union  permanent  out-of-work  benefits :  Boilermakers,  Black- 
smiths, Bookbinders,  Cloth  Hat  and  Cap  Makers.  Commer- 
cial Telegraphers,  Glass  Workers,  Hotel  and  Restaurant 
Employees,  Lace  Operatives,  Ladies'  Garment  Workers, 
Spinners,  and  Wood  Carvers.  In  the  building  trades  very 
few  local  unions  maintain  out-of-work  funds. 

39  Proceedings,  1901,  p.  92. 

40  Proceedings,  1901,  p.  91. 

41  The  Survey,  February  20,  1915,  p.  550. 

42  Pattern  Makers'  Journal,  April,  1906,  p.  13. 

43  Ibid.,  May,  1914,  p.  20. 

44  Ibid.,  May,  1908,  p.  3. 

45  The  Survey,  February  20,  1915,  p.  55<>. 


UNEMPLOYMENT  INSURANCE  145 

An  indirect  form  of  unemployment  benefit  is  the  exemp- 
tion of  those  who  are  out  of  work  from  the  payment  of 
dues  and  assessments.  This  rule  is  found  in  the  Black- 
smiths, Boilermakers,  Brewery  Workers,  Cigar  Makers, 
Diamond  Workers,  Glass  Workers,  Granite  Cutters,  Hat- 
ters, Iron  Holders,  Leather  Workers  on  Horse  Goods, 
Lithographers,  Locomotive  Firemen,  Machinists,  Metal  Pol- 
ishers, United  Mine  Workers,  Pattern  Makers,  Photo-En- 
gravers, Piano  and  Organ  Workers,  Pulp,  Sulphite  and 
Paper  Mill  Operatives,  Stove  Mounters,  and  Western  Fed- 
eration of  Miners.  In  other  unions,  such  as  the  Flint  Glass 
Workers  and  Printers,  where  the  members  are  taxed  in 
proportion  to  the  amount  of  their  wages,  the  unemployed 
are  automatically  freed  from  the  payment  of  dues. 

The  dues  of  those  unions  which  have  developed  strong 
beneficiary  systems  have  naturally  increased  with  the  intro- 
duction of  each  new  benefit,  and  in  some  cases  amount  to 
five  per  cent  of  the  members'  wages.  The  unemployed 
member  thus  finds  it  difficult  at  times  to  remain  in  good 
standing.  Moreover,  in  some  cases  those  who  have  been 
in  arrears  for  a  certain  number  of  weeks  are  excluded  from 
union  benefits.  On  account  of  these  circumstances  about 
twenty  national  unions  exempt  the  unemployed  from  pay- 
ment of  dues  so  that  they  can  be  retained  as  members  and 
be  entitled  to  the  various  benefits. 

The  general  character  of  these  provisions  is  much  the 
same.  The  Iron  Molders  exempt  unemployed  members 
from  payment  of  dues  for  a  period  of  not  exceeding  thir- 
teen weeks  in  any  one  year.  Those  who  have  paid  dues  for 
the  preceding  six  months  are  entitled  to  this  exemption.46 
This  rule  was  adopted  in  October,  1897,  and  to  the  first  of 
January,  1915,  the  cost  of  the  system  was  $3i6,i68.47 

The  United  Mine  Workers,  on  account  of  seasonal  unem- 
ployment in  the  trade,  exempt  members  from  the  payment 
of  dues  when  unemployed.  A  member  who  has  been  idle 

46  Constitution,  1912,  art.  18,  sec.  i. 

47  Molders'  Journal,  February,  1915,  p.  112. 
10 


146      UNEMPLOYMENT  AND  AMERICAN   TRADE  UNIONS 

for  one  month  is  excused  from  payment  of  all  dues  until  he 
again  obtains  employment.48  The  Granite  Cutters  provide 
that  any  member  in  good  standing  who  is  unemployed  shall 
be  exempted  from  one-half  of  the  regular  dues.49  The 
Metal  Polishers  excuse  members  who  are  unemployed  from 
the  payment  of  dues  for  three  months  after  four  weeks  of 
idleness.60 

In  view  of  the  fact  that  the  out-of-work  benefit  is  one  of 
the  devices  by  which  trade  unions  protect  the  standard  rate 
and  the  working  conditions  by  relieving  members  of  the 
necessity  of  accepting  less  favorable  terms  aind  conditions, 
it  is  difficult  to  understand  why  the  out-of-work  benefit  is 
not  more  widely  used.  In  the  greater  number  of  unions 
the  officers  are  staunch  advocates  of  the  system,  and  there  is 
no  more  ardent  supporter  of  out-of-work  benefits  than 
President  Gompers  of  the  American  Federation  of  Labor. 
At  the  New  York  convention  of  the  American  Federation 
of  Labor  in  1898,  the  delegates  went  on  record  as  endorsing 
the  payment  of  the  benefit  and  urged  all  affiliated  unions  to 
establish  such  a  system.61 

Two  reasons  can  be  stated  for  the  slight  development  of 
the  out-of-work  benefit  in  American  trade  unions ;  first,  the 
unwillingness  of  the  average  union  member  to  acquiesce  in 
the  necessary  increase  of  dues;  and  second,  the  apparent 
inadequacy  of  the  administrative  agencies  of  the  union  to 
secure  a  just  distribution  of  the  benefit. 

The  first  of  these  hindrances  to  the  establishment  of  the 
out-of-work  benefit  needs  little  comment.  The  average 
workingman  joins  a  trade  union  chiefly  from  the  desire  to 
carry  a  union  card  and  participate  in  the  better  conditions 
secured  by  the  union.  The  matter  of  benefits,  and  espe- 
cially out-of-work  benefits,  is  of  secondary  importance. 
He  wants  to  be  a  member  of  the  union,  but  he  also  wants 
the  dues  to  be  as  small  as  possible. 

48  Constitution,  1914,  art.  14,  sec.  23. 

49  Constitution,  1912,  sec.  134. 

60  Constitution,  1913,  art.  17,  sec.  3. 
51  Proceedings,  1899,  p.  5677. 


UNEMPLOYMENT  INSURANCE  147 

The  second  hindrance  grows  chiefly  out  of  the  personal 
acquaintance  of  the  local  union  officials  with  the  members. 
The  experience  of  the  Cigar  Makers,  and  for  that  matter, 
the  history  of  any  trade  union  benefit,  shows  that  there  are 
always  local  union  officials  who  pay  benefits  which  should 
not  have  been  paid.  The  disbursing  agencies  must  be  given 
considerable  discretion  in  determining  whether  or  not  the 
applicants  are  entitled  to  the  benefit.  Further,  the  local 
officials  seem  unable  to  deal  strictly  with  a  member  who 
abandons  a  job  on  plausible  grounds.  The  experience  of 
the  New  York  local  union  of  the  Typographical  Union  with 
an  out-of-work  benefit  may  be  cited.  A  member  of  that 
organization  writes:  "We  found  that  a  number  of  men 
each  year  drew  the  full  amount  that  was  permitted  them 
under  the  laws  regulating  the  fund,  and  that  these  men  could 
best  be  described  as  '  panhandlers.'  The  abuses  in  our  case 
eventually  became  so  flagrant  that  the  fund  was  abolished 
upon  the  report  of  an  investigating  committee  to  the  effect 
that  the  majority  of  the  beneficiaries  of  the  fund  belonged 
to  this  dissolute  class."52  The  unions  have  specifically  set 
forth  in  the  rules  on  the  subject  the  manner  in  which  the 
benefit  systems  are  to  be  administered  and  the  various  con- 
ditions under  which  the  unemployed  members  shall  become 
entitled  to  the  benefit.  The  systems  generally  have  been 
well  planned  but  poorly  administered. 

Since  the  establishment  by  Great  Britain  of  a  compre- 
hensive insurance  plan  some  of  the  American  trade  union 
officials  have  inaugurated  campaigns  for  the  adoption  of  a 
similar  scheme  by  this  government.53  Inasmuch  as  the  con- 
census of  opinion  among  recent  writers  on  the  subject  is  in 
favor  of  utilizing  the  trade  union  in  a  scheme  of  govern- 
ment insurance,54  it  is  not  surprising  that  American  repre- 

52  A.  J.  Portenar,  Problems  of  Organized  Labor,  p.  73. 

53  The  text  of  the  British  Insurance  Act  is  contained  in  Bulletin 
of  the  United  States  Bureau  of  Labor,  No.  102. 

54  I.  G.  Gibbon,  Unemployment  Insurance,  p.  251 ;  Cyril  Jackson, 
Unemployment  and  Trade  Unions,  p.  29;  Henry  R.  Seager,  "  Outline 
of  a  Program  of  Social  Legislation,"  in  Proceedings  of  the  first 
Annual  Meeting  of  the  American  Association  for  Labor  Legislation, 
1907,  p.  87. 


148       UNEMPLOYMENT   AND  AMERICAN   TRADE   UNIONS 

sentatives  of  organized  labor  demand  that  the  trade  unions 
should  be  given  the  right  to  administer  the  benefit  among 
their  own  members.65 

We  have  seen  that  three  national  unions  have  established 
unemployment  benefits,  that  a  few  more  have  provided 
emergency  relief  funds  for  those  out  of  work,  and  that  a 
small  percentage  of  the  local  unions  have  regular  benefits 
for  the  unemployed.  Under  such  conditions  one  might  ex- 
pect to  find  the  average  unemployed  trade  unionist  in  as 
bad  a  predicament  as  the  unemployed  non-unionist.  But 
such  is  by  no  means  the  case.  There  is  scarcely  one  Ameri- 
can local  union  which  does  not  in  some  form  or  other 
contribute  towards  the  support  of  its  unemployed  members 
when  they  are  in  need  of  assistance.  A  member  out  of 
work  is  rarely  turned  away  from  the  union  without  receiv- 
ing some  assistance.  In  some  cases  it  may  take  the  form  of 
a  loan  of  a  few  dollars,  but  his  union  will  rarely  allow  him 
to  suffer  from  want.  The  usual  procedure  is  for  a  friend 
of  the  unemployed  to  announce  at  a  meeting  of  the  local 
union  that  a  brother  member  is  unemployed  and  in  need  of 
money  to  pay  the  rent  and  secure  the  necessities  of  life. 
With  scarcely  any  further  remarks,  the  union  votes  to  do- 
nate a  sum  of  money  to  the  member.  In  other  cases  the 
local  union  sets  aside  a  certain  sum  of  money  for  the  relief 
of  the  unemployed,  and  appoints  a  committee  which  has 
complete  control  over  the  granting  of  aid. 

Frequently  the  unions,  in  periods  of  general  business  de- 
pression, maintain  relief  agencies  for  their  unemployed.  In 
1915  some  two  hundred  Jewish  trade  unions  of  New  York 
City  opened  headquarters  on  the  lower  East  Side  and  gave 
out  groceries  to  their  unemployed  members.86  From  January 
I  to  May  i  of  the  same  year,  the  bricklayers'  local  union 
of  Toronto,  Ontario,  donated  372  baskets  of  groceries  and 

55  G.  W.  Perkins,  in  American  Labor  Legislation  Review,  June, 
1913,  p.  236;  T.  J.  Dolan,  in  the  Steam  Shovel  and  Dredge  Mun, 
April,  1915,  p.  380;  Proceedings  of  the  Massachusetts  Federation  of 
Labor,  1915. 

56  The    American    Labor    Legislation    Review,    November,    1915, 
p.  104. 


UNEMPLOYMENT   INSURANCE  149 

many  tons  of  coal  to  their  unemployed  members.57  Of 
course,  these  relief  agencies  are  marked  with  the  stigma  of 
charity  and  consequently  only  those  who  are  in  dire  need 
apply  to  them.  The  system  is  far  from  ideal.  The  un- 
employed are  assisted  only  when  they  are  in  great  need,  and 
those  who  have  been  fortunate  and  wise  enough  to  save  for 
the  days  of  unemployment  do  not  receive  any  aid  from  the 
system.  But,  as  one  trade  unionist  said,  "  It  is  better  than 
that  provided  for  the  non-unionist." 

The  effectiveness  of  even  so  crude  a  system  is  shown  by 
the'  fact  that  union  members  are  rarely  found  among  the 
applicants  to  organized  charities.  Those  associated  with 
charity  organizations  adequately  appreciate  the  valuable 
social  services  performed  by  the  trade  unions.  A  writer  on 
the  subject  says,  "  Charity  workers  testify  to  the  fact  that 
during  business  depressions  when  the  unemployed  must  be 
cared  for  by  the  thousands,  scarcely  a  single  member  of  a 
trade  union  has  applied  for  relief  either  to  the  cities  or  to 
philanthropic  organizations."58  The  Secretary  of  the  United 
Charities  of  St.  Paul,  Minnesota,  stated  that  in  1914-1915 
"  The  trade  unions  with  their  benefit  features  have  been  the 
saving  grace  in  the  situation  here."59  In  December,  1913, 
the  city  of  Seattle,  Washington,  provided  special  work  for 
the  unemployed,  and  of  the  1300  men  who  applied  for  work 
only  six  were  members  of  trade  unions.60  The  chairman  of 
the  relief  work  in  Chicago  during  the  severe  season  of  1893— 
1894  reported  that  not  a  single  member  of  a  trade  union  in 
that  city  applied  for  aid  either  to  the  city  or  to  the  philan- 
thropic organizations.61 

As  further  proof  of  this  fact,  the  report  of  the  Com- 
mission of  Industrial  Relations  may  be  quoted :  "  It  is 

The  Bricklayer,  Mason  and  Plasterer,  May,  1915,  p.  104. 
58Adna  F.  Weber,  quoted  in  the  Bricklayer  and  Mason,  January, 
1902,  p.  7. 

59  Quoted  in  the  American  Labor  Legislation  Review,  November, 
IQI5,  P.  589. 

60  Associated  Press  Dispatch. 

61  Bulletin  of  the  United  States  Department  of  Labor,  Number  22, 
May,  1899,  p.  400. 


I5O      UNEMPLOYMENT   AND   AMERICAN    TRADE   UNIONS 

significant  that  trade  union  members  are  practically  never 
found  among  the  applicants  for  .charity  during  periods  of 
unemployment.  They  may  be  unemployed,  but  they  are 
in  some  way  cared  for,  either  by  having  work  found  for 
them,  or  by  systematic  or  voluntary  relief."62  With  but  few 
exceptions,  those  applying  to  charitable  organizations  as 
union  members  are  found  to  be  expelled  members  or  in 
arrears  with  their  dues.63 

62  Final  Report  of  the  Commission  on  Industrial  Relations,  1915, 

P-  175. 

63  Mr.  C.  C.  Rohr,  a  member  of  the  Economic  Seminary  of  Johns 
Hopkins  University,  in  1911-1912  made  an  investigation  of  500  cases 
of  the  Federated  Charities  of  Baltimore  City.    The  Charity  records 
showed  that  of  the  500  applicants  19  were  members  of  trade  unions. 
Upon  investigation,  however,  nine  of  these  were  found  never  to  have 
been  associated  with  any  union.    And  of  the  remaining  ten  only  two 
were  union  members  in  good  standing  at  the  time  when  the  period 
of  unemployment  began.    One  of  these  was  unable  to  live  upon  the 
strike  benefits  of  his  union,  and  the  other  was  a  member  of  a  local 
union  on  strike  which  had  expended  its  entire  strike  fund. 


INDEX 


American  Federation  of  Labor, 
15,  Si,  52,  53,  70,  93,  123,  130, 
1377138,  146. 

American  Tinplate  Company, 
119. 

Apprenticeship,  36-37. 

Bakers  and  Confectioners  of 
Chicago,  62. 

Bakery  and  Confectionery 
Workers'  International  Union, 
64,  67,  84,  120,  124,  140,  143. 

Balsinger,  President,  84. 

Barbers'  International  Union, 
Journeymen,  64. 

Barnes,  Charles  E.,  33. 

Barnett,  George  E.,  44,  108,  124 
(note),  140  (note). 

Benefits.     See  Insurance. 

Beveridge,  W.  H.,  19. 

Blacksmiths  and  Helpers,  In- 
ternational Brotherhood  of, 
59,  67,  84,  123,  144,  145. 

Boilermakers,  Iron  Shipbuilders 
and  Helpers  of  America,  In- 
ternational Brotherhood  of, 
15,  60,  123,  129,  144,  145. 

Bookbinders,  International 
Brotherhood  of,  82,  87,  91, 120, 
144-  • 

Boot  and  Shoe  Workers'  Union, 
87,  120,  141,  143. 

Boston  Free  Employment  Office, 
71- 

Brandeis,  Louis  D.,  113. 

Brass  and  Composition  Metal 
Workers,  Polishers,  and  Buf- 
fers, United  Brotherhood  of, 
59- 

Brewery  Workmen,  Interna- 
tional Union  of  the  United,  39, 
42,  64,  67,  108,  121,  122,  129, 
141,  143,  145. 

Bricklayers,  Masons  and  Plas- 
terers, International  Union  of, 
17,  42,  54,  65,  84,  86,  87,  88,  90, 

91,   IO2. 


Bridge  and  Structural  Iron 
Workers,  International  Asso- 
ciation of,  40,  52,  60,  65,  84,  86, 
87,  89,  90,  93. 

Business  agent,  58  ff;  salary  of, 
59;  duties  of,  60;  why  em- 
ployers apply  to,  62-63 ;  one  of 
the  union  members,  64. 

"  Calling  around,"  66. 

Cards,  interchange  of,  42-43. 

Carpenters  and  Joiners,  United 
Brotherhood  of,  40,  42,  52,  59, 
65,  86,  87,  88,  107,  139. 

Carter,  President,  82,  107. 

Chicago,  Burlington  and  Quincy 
Strike,  82. 

Chicago,  Rock  Island  and  Pa- 
cific Railway,  123 

Cigar  Makers,  International  Un- 
ion of,  32,  58,  67,  69,  86,  90,  94, 
102,  103,  104,  130,  134,  135,  139, 

145,  147- 

Cloth  Hat  and  Cap  Makers, 
United,  no,  115,  126,  144. 

Commercial  Telegraphers, 
Brotherhood  of,  42,  120,  144. 

Commisison  of  Industrial  Rela- 
tions, 149. 

Coopers,  International  Union  of, 
87,  1 20. 

Crown,  Cork  and  Seal  Opera- 
tives, 123. 

Diamond    Workers'    Protective 

Union,  130,  135-137,  145- 
Dismissal  of  workmen,  123  ff. 
Dobbins,  Secretary,  96. 
Dobson,  Secretary,  17  (note),  85. 
Dovetailing  of  trades,  30-31. 
Drawing  of  lots,  68. 
Drayer,  Secretary,  86. 
Duffy,  Secretary,  139. 
Duncan,  President,  52,  56,  96. 
Dunderdale,  Superintendent,  71. 

Efficiency  of  Workmen,  125-126. 


152 


INDEX 


Electrical  Workers,  Interna- 
tional Union  of,  15,  37,  38,  60, 
84,  89,  93,  108. 

Emergency  funds,  138. 

Employment,  distribution  of,  109 
ff. ;  ways  of  distributing,  109- 
124;  conditions  effecting  un- 
ion policies  toward,  125-128; 
union  objections  to,  128-129. 

Employment,  subsidiary,  20-21  ; 
varies  with  the  trade,  31 ; 
through  help  of  fellow-work- 
men, 64;  through  advertise- 
ments, 73-74. 

Employment  bureaus,  public,  69 
ff. ;  state,  69;  employers,  73; 
religious  and  charitable,  73. 

Employment  bureaus,  union,  57 
ff. ;  need  of,  varies,  58;  agen- 
cies for  securing  help,  58; 
methods  of  choosing  work- 
men, 67  ff. 

"  Five  day  "  rule,  123-124. 

"  Fliers,"  76. 

Flint  Glass  Workers'  Union, 
American,  17,  19,  30,  39,  40,  42, 
64,  78,  86,  87,  92,  94,  96,  103, 
104,  no,  117,  123,  128,  138,  145. 

Fluctuation,  19  ff. ;  remedies  for, 
29-31. 

Furuseth,  President,  70. 

Garland,  President,  84,  119. 

Garment  Workers'  Union,  La- 
dies, 42,  58,  no,  112,  123,  126, 
144- 

Garment  Workers,  United,  42, 
58,  87,  no,  114. 

Glass  Bottle  Blowers'  Associa- 
tion, 16,  42,  76,  119,  123,  138. 

Glass  Workers'  International 
Association,  Amalgamated,  122, 
144,  145- 

Glove  Workers'  Union,  Interna- 
tional, no,  115. 

Gompers,  Samuel,  52,  53,  70,  95, 
131,  146. 

Granite  Cutters'  International 
Association,  52,  54,  56,  75,  87, 
94,  95,  103,  140,  145,  146. 

Hatters     of     North     America, 

United,  66,  67,  no,  115,  145. 
Hayes,  President,  77,  120. 


Hays,  Secretary,  83. 

Hotel  and  Restaurant  Em- 
ployees' International  Alliance, 
72,  144- 

Hurst,  President,  131. 

Iffland,  Secretary,  143. 

Illinois  Free  Employment 
Agency,  71. 

Indiana  Typographical  Confer- 
ence, 88. 

Industrial  depressions,  effect  of, 
28-29. 

Insurance,  national  unions  hav- 
ing, 130-141 ;  systems  in  local 
unions,  141-144;  indirect  form 
of,  145-146;  reasons  for  not 
having,  146-147;  campaigns 
for  government,  147. 

Iron,  Steel  and  Tin  Workers, 
Amalgamated  Association  of, 
84,  no,  118,  123,  140. 

Journals,  86  ff. 

Kelley,  President,  49,  51. 
Kunzler,  Secretary,  96. 

Labor  supply,  methods  of  ad- 
justing, 75-76;  systems  in  dif- 
ferent unions,  76-90;  failure 
to  solve  problems,  90-92;  hin- 
drances in  the  movement  of, 
107. 

Lace  Operatives,  Chartered  So- 
ciety of  the  Amalgamated,  120, 

144- 

Lathers,  International  Union  of 
Wood,  Wire  and  Metal,  86. 

Laundry  Workers'  International 
Union,  120. 

Lawlor,  Martin,  67  (note),  115. 

Lawrence,  Vice-President,  88. 

Leather  Workers  on  Horse 
Goods,  United  Brotherhood 
of,  83,  87,  94,  99,  103,  104,  120, 
145- 

Lithographers'  International  Pro- 
tective and  Beneficial  Associa- 
tion, 15,  58,  64,  67,  79,  88,  94, 
100,  120,  126,  140,  143,  145. 

Lloyd,  President,  139. 

Locomotive  Engineers,  Grand 
International  Brotherhood  of, 
45- 


INDEX 


153 


Locomotive  Firemen  and  En- 
ginemen,  Brotherhood  of,  81, 

145- 

Lots,  drawing  of,  68. 
Lynch,  President,  45,  83,  88,  140. 

McGuire,  P.  J.,  52,  139. 

Machinists,  International  Asso- 
ciation of,  39,  40,  47,  59,  60,  67, 
94,  99,  103,  123,  129,  145. 

Maintenance  of  Way  Employees, 
International  Brotherhood  of, 
42. 

Marble  Workers,  International 
Association  of,  92. 

Maryland  Federation  of  Labor, 

71. 

Massachusetts  Bureau  of  Sta- 
tistics, 12,  21,  25. 

Massachusetts  Employment  Bu- 
reau, 72. 

Membership,  limited,  35-36. 

Metal  Polishers,  Buffers,  Plat- 
ers, Brass  Molders  and  Brass 
and  Silver  Workers,  Interna- 
tional Union  of,  15,  54,  59,  120, 
123,  141,  145,  146. 

Miller,  Secretary  Hugo,  101, 135. 

Mine  Workers,  United,  42,  67, 
no. 

Miners,  Western  Federation  of, 
42,  1 10,  145. 

Mitchell,  John,  in. 

Molders'  Union,  International, 
15.  59.  86,  120,  123,  129,  145. 

Murphy,  President,  38,  108. 

New  England  Typographical 
Union,  88. 

New  Hampshire  Bureau  of  La- 
bor, 14. 

New  York  Department'  of  La- 
bor, 10,  13  (note),  14  (note), 
21,  25,  32. 

New  York  Public  Employment 
Bureau,  71. 

Normal  day,  shortening  of,  50- 
53- 

Northern  Pacific  Railroad,  45- 
46. 

O'Connell,  President,  51,  100. 
Out-of-work     list,     compulsory, 

67 ;  optional,  67. 
Output,  restriction  of,  46-50. 
Overtime,  regulation  of,  54-56. 


Painters,  Decorators,  and  Paper- 
hangers,  Brotherhood  of,  16, 
42,  52,  60,  87,  88,  91,  101,  107, 
140. 

Paper  Makers,  International 
Brotherhood  of,  120. 

Pattern  Makers'  League,  17,  21, 
28,  59,  60,  62,  67,  81,  120,  123, 
140,  144,  145. 

Perkins,  President,  104. 

Permit  system,  37-41 ;  effect  on 
transference  of  workmen,  108. 

Pfeiffer,  Secretary,  84. 

Photo-Engravers'  Union,  Inter- 
national, 36,  54,  64,  67,  79,  87, 
120,  141,  144,  145. 

Piano,  Organ  and  Musical  In- 
strument Workers'  Interna- 
tional Union,  145. 

Plasterers'  International  Asso- 
ciation, Operative,  40,  42,  86. 

Plumbers,  Gas  Fitters,  Steam 
Fitters  and  Steam  Fitters 
Helpers'  •  United  Association 
of  Journeymen,  15,  37,  41,  48, 
51,  86,  102,  140. 

Potters,  International  Brother- 
hood of  Operative,  15,  64,  80, 
116,  141. 

Prescott,   President,   139-140. 

Printers.  See  Typographical 
Union. 

Proebstle,  39  (note),  122,  143 
(note). 

Pulp,  Sulphite  and  Paper  Mill 
Workers,  International  Broth- 
erhood of,  145. 

Railroad  Telegraphers,  Order 
of,  42. 

Railroad  Trainmen,  Brotherhood 
of,  82. 

Railway  Carmen,  Brotherhood 
of,  42. 

Railway  Conductors,  Brother- 
hood of,  82. 

Rock  Island  Federated  Trades, 
123. 

Rotation  of  workers,  120-123. 

Rowe,  President,  40. 

Sanitary  Manufacturing  Potters' 

Association,  116. 
Seamen's    Union,    International. 

67. 
Sears,  Mr.,  71. 


154 


INDEX 


Seniority  rights,  43-46;  objec- 
tions to,  44;  defense  of,  44- 
45;  effect  on  transferring  of 
workmen,  107. 

Sheet  Metal  Workers'  Interna- 
tional Alliance,  Amalgamated, 
67,  86,  88,  123. 

Sheppard,  President,  82. 

"  Shop  collector,"  64. 

Short,  President,  41. 

Short-time,  working  of,  noff. 

"  Six-day-law,"  55,  124. 

Skemp,  Secretary,  16  (note),  91. 

Smith,  President,  117. 

Spinners'  Union,  International, 
54,  144- 

Stationary  Firemen,  Interna- 
tional Brotherhood  of,  42. 

Statistics,  gS. ;  sources  of,  10; 
of  New  York  Department  of 
Labor,  12;  of  the  Massachu- 
setts Bureau,  12-14;  of  New 
Hampshire  Bureau  of  Labor, 
14;  reasons  for  failure  to  col- 
lect, 14-15;  unions  that  col- 
lect, 15-20;  factors  overlooked 
in,  20-21 ;  conclusions  drawn 
from,  23  ff. 

Steam  Engineers,  International 
Union  of,  42. 

Steam,  Hot  Water  and  Power 
Pipe  Fitters  and  Helpers,  In- 
ternational Association  of,  36, 
41- 

Steam  Shovel  and  Dredge  Men, 
International  Brotherhood  of, 
72. 

Stcne  Cutters'  Association, 
Journeymen,  81,  86. 

Stove  Mounters'  International 
Union,  84,  120,  145. 

Strasser,  President,  131 

Street  and  Electric  Railway  Em- 
ployees, Amalgamated  Asso- 
ciation of,  120. 

Tailors'  National  Union,  Jour- 
neymen, no,  114. 

Teamsters,  International  Broth- 
erhood of,  42,  59. 

Textile  Workers,  United,  no, 
"5. 

Trades,  dovetailing  of,  30-31. 

Traveling,  statistics  of,  25 ;  ex- 
penses for,  93. 

Traveling  loans,  failure  of,  94; 


national  unions  having,  95- 
102;  local  unions  having,  102- 
103;  cost  of,  104. 

Typographia,  Deutsch-Ameri- 
kanische,  64,  84,  04,  101,  103, 
104,  130,  133,  134,  135,  139. 

Typographical  Association  of 
New  York  City,  141-142. 

Typographical  Union,  Interna- 
tional, 43,  44,  47,  55,  67,  71,  87, 
88,  102,  108,  124,  129,  139,  140, 
141,  142,  145,  147- 

Unemployment,  in  different  lo- 
calities, 23  ff. ;  relative  volume 
and  character  of,  28;  methods 
of  relieving,  29;  remedies  for 
seasonal,  31 ;  union  theory  of, 
34  ff. 

Unions,  realizing  benefit  of  sta- 
tistics, 15;  methods  of  reliev- 
ing unemployment,  29;  atti- 
tude toward  amount  of  work, 
34;  importance  of  headquar- 
ters of,  65;  methods  of  adjust- 
ing labor  supply,  76  ff. ;  failure 
to  solve  problem  of  transfer- 
ring members,  90;  paying 
traveling  loans,  94;  policy 
toward  distribution  of  em- 
ployment, 109  ff. ;  conditions 
effecting  policy  of,  125;  objec- 
tions to  distribution  of  em- 
ployment, 128-129 ;  relief  agen- 
cies in,  148. 

Linked  States  Potters'  Associa- 
tion, 116. 

Universal  Card  System,  43. 

Voitle,  President,  39. 

Watch  Case  Engravers'  Interna- 
tional Association,  123. 

White  Rats  Actors'  Union,  94, 
98,  103. 

Wilson,  James,  21  (note),  22,  81 
(note). 

Wisconsin  State  Federation  of 
Labor,  15,  50  (note). 

Woll,  President,  54,  8p. 

Wood  Carvers'  Association,  In- 
ternational, 16,  86,  144. 

"  Work  fund  "  theory,  35,  42. 

Workmen,  dismissal  of,  123  ff. ; 
efficiency  of,  125-126. 


THE   LABOR  LAW  OF  MARYLAND 


'»>*    } 

SERIES  xxxvn  No.  a 

JOHNS  HOPKINS  UNIVERSITY  STUDIES 

IN 

HISTORICAL  AND  POLITICAL  SCIENCE 

Under  the  Direction  of  the 

Departments  of  History,  Political  Economy,  and 
Political  Science 


THE   LABOR  LAW  OF  MARYLAND 


BY 


MALCOLM  H.  LAUCHHEIMER,  PH.D. 
First  Lieutenant,  Judge  Advocate,  A.  E.  F. 


BALTIMORE 
THE  JOHNS  HOPKINS  PRESS 

1919 


COPYRIGHT  1919  BY 
THE  JOHNS  HOPKINS  PRESS 


PRESS  OF 

THE  NEW  ERA  PRINTING  COMPANY 
LANCASTER.  PA. 


CONTENTS 

PACE 

PREFACE    vii 

CHAPTER  I.    INTRODUCTION  9 

The  Problem  of  the  Labor  Law  9 

Maryland  Conditions  16 

CHAPTER  II.    THE  LABOR  UNION 19 

The  Law  of  Union  Activities  19 

Statutes  Relating  to  Unionism  39 

CHAPTER  III.    THE  WORKMEN'S  COMPENSATION  LAW 46 

History   , . . .  46 

The  Present  Law  as  Social  Legislation 5  * 

The  Constitutionality  of  the  Law 70 

CHAPTER  IV.    THE  CONDITIONS  OF  EMPLOYMENT  76 

Regulation  by  Commission   77 

Fire  Protection  81 

Protective  Devices 85 

Sanitation   86 

The  Tenement  Law  90 

CHAPTER  V.    THE  TERMS  OF  EMPLOYMENT  94 

Foreword    94 

Prohibitions  of  Employment  96 

Hours    loo 

Wages    104 

CHAPTER  VI.    SOME  MISCELLANEOUS  LAWS "3 

Licenses    1 13 

Attachments  and  Liens  i  16 

Child  Welfare   "7 

State  Employment  i*9 

CHAPTER  VII.    THE  ADMINISTRATIVE  SYSTEM  122 

State  Board  of  Labor  and  Statistics 123 

State  Board  of  Health  133 

Minor  Administrative  Agencies  >35 

Suggestions  for  Reform  136 

*..  y 

CHAPTER  VIII.    THE  STATE  IN  RELATION  TO  LABOR H5 

v 


PREFACE 

This  monograph  needs  little  preface.  The  method  of 
study  is  local  and  intensive,  but  I  have  endeavored  to  draw 
some  general  conclusions  from  the  specific  subject-matter 
treated.  The  book,  as  its  title  implies,  is  neither  a  text 
book  nor  a  reference  book,  though  it  may  serve  to  a  slight 
degree  in  the  latter  capacity,  but  a  dissertation. 

I  take  this  means  of  expressing  my  gratitude  to  Prof. 
W.  W.  Willoughby,  who  served  as  my  inspiration  and 
rendered  me  much  assistance  in  the  preparation  of  this 
monograph,  and  also  to  Prof.  George  E.  Barnett  and  to 
Miss  Anna  Herkner,  former  Assistant-Chief  of  the  Mary- 
land Bureau  of  Statistics.  Various  others  to  whom  I  am 
indebted  are  mentioned  throughout  the  text. 

The  monograph  was  completed  towards  the  end  of  1916 
and,  because  of  the  author's  participation  in  the  war,  it  has 
been  impossible  to  bring  it  up  to  date  in  many  particulars. 

M.  H.  L. 


rii 


THE  LABOR  LAW  OF  MARYLAND 


CHAPTER  I 
INTRODUCTION 

The  Problem  of  the  Labor  Law. — The  labor  law  of  a 
state  is  a  peculiar  combination  of  unwritten  and  statute 
law.  It  differs  from  most  law  in  that  it  is  not  merely  an 
evolution  of  the  customary  law  of  a  community,  but  is  a 
definite  attempt  by  the  community  to  solve,  now  by  the 
common  law,  now  by  statute,  an  acute  social  problem.  It 
does  to  a  degree  reflect  the  customary  morality  of  the  com- 
munity, but  this  not  unconsciously,  as,  for  example,  in  the 
case  of  commercial  law,  but  as  a  conscious  adoption  of  an 
ethical  principle  for  a  political  norm.  A  complete  under- 
standing of  labor  law  requires,  therefore,  not  merely  a 
delving  into  jurisprudence,  but  also  into  political  the- 
ory. We  must  study,  not  merely  the  law  itself,  but  the 
law  as  an  expression  of  the  relation  of  the  state  to  its  citi- 
zens ;  the  labor  law  in  truth  is  one  of  the  most  interesting 
media  in  which  to  study  the  extent  to  which  the  state  can 
justify  its  interference  in  the  private  life  of  individuals. 
Accordingly,  although  this  study  will  be  primarily  a  critical 
analysis  and  description  of  actual  laws  in  practical  opera- 
tion, there  will  necessarily  be  in  it  an  undercurrent  of  specu- 
lative political  theory. 

The  state,  then,  in  its  labor  law  sets  out  to  solve  a  very 
definite  social  problem,  the  problem  of  industrial  unrest, 
the  problem  of  reconciling  and  placating  labor  and  capital. 
The  history  of  this  activity  of  the  state  stretches  back  six 
or  seven  centuries,  and  the  policy  of  the  state  has  varied 
from  complete  aloofness  to  intimate  intervention. 

9 


IO  THE  LABOR  LAW   OF   MARYLAND  [l$6 

Logically  and  perhaps  historically  the  first  instrumental- 
ity made  use  of  by  the  state  in  meeting  the  labor  problem 
is  the  common  law.  This  results,  not  from  an  active  in- 
tent on  the  part  of  the  state  to  solve  any  problem,  but  from 
a  quiescent  attitude  towards  an  unimportant  phenomenon. 
The  common  law  is  turned  to  before  the  labor  problem 
assumes  any  special  characteristics  of  its  own,  and  the 
various  cases  are  settled  according  to  the  general  principles 
of  the  common  law  as  laid  down  in  cases  between  individ- 
uals who  are  in  no  special  relation  to  each  other.  If,  in  the 
beginning,  as  is  usually  the  case,  no  economic  question 
obtrudes  into  the  case,  but  the  matter  is  one  of  pure  law, 
the  decision  based  on  former  precedents  will  work  substan- 
tial justice.  When,  on  the  other  hand,  the  relative  economic 
position  of  the  two  parties  is  of  importance,  decisions  based 
on  pure  law  will  not  be  adequate  and  will  often  entirely 
fail  to  settle  the  question  at  bar.  When,  as  always  hap- 
pens, the  economic  status  of  the  parties  does  not  merit 
attention  until  after  the  deciding  of  cases  involving  similar 
matters,  but  not  calling  into  question  the  economic  relation, 
it  is  practically  impossible  for  the  judges  when  the  economic 
question  is  presented  to  them  to  disregard  the  precedents 
and  to  dispense  economic  justice  and  not  justice  according 
to  law.  Common  law  does,  as  is  often  said,  progress  and 
grow  with  the  times,  but  more  often  legislation  is  necessary 
to  make  it  entirely  adequate.  Thus  the  common  law  of 
negligence  did  not  meet  the  requirements  of  industrial 
accidents,  and  employers'  liability  and  compensation  laws 
were  the  result.  Thus  the  common  law  of  individual  bar- 
gaining and  competition  does  not  seem  to  meet  the  require- 
ments of  collective  bargaining,  and  legislation  recognizing 
the  validity  of  unionism  is  being  demanded. 

A  more  serious  inadequacy  of  the  common  law,  how- 
ever, as  a  means  of  solving  the  labor  problem  arises  from 
the  inherent  characteristic  of  that  law  as  a  system  of  juris- 
prudence. The  common  law  is  remedial,  compensatory; 
labor  conditions  call  for  regulation,  prohibition.  The  com- 


I  $  /]  INTRODUCTION  II 

mon  law  seeks  to  relieve  the  sting  of  a  wrong  after  it  has 
been  committed;  labor  conditions  necessitate  regulations 
making  impossible  the  commission  of  the  wrong.  A  close 
scrutiny  of  the  entire  field  of  the  common  law  will  reveal 
no  principles  which  could  support  such  movements  as  the 
"safety  first"  and  "living  wage"  propagandas.  Even 
equity  with  its  canons  of  preventive  relief  against  irrepara- 
ble injuries  does  not  furnish  a  proper  foundation  for  the 
state  control  of  labor  conditions.  Thus,  though  the  state 
could  and  does  depend  to  a  great  degree  upon  its  unwritten 
law  in  solving  the  economic  problem  of  labor  and  capital, 
it  must  and  does  every  day  more  and  more  seek  the  answer 
in  social  legislation. 

But  the  first  manifestations  of  state  activity  in  the  field 
of  labor  legislation  were  of  an  entirely  different  nature 
from  what  is  now  usually  referred  to  as  -social  legislation. 
These  laws,  of  which  the  Statute  of  Laborers,  passed  after 
the  Black  Death,  with  its  later  variations  and  the  Eliza- 
bethan Statute  of  Apprentices  are  the  classical  examples, 
were  not  based  upon  any  economic  principle  of  the  welfare 
of  the  laborer,  but,  in  so  far  as  any  general  principle  of 
economics  was  involved,  upon  a  desire  to  keep  low  the  cost 
of  commodities.  Rather,  it  may  be  said,  these  laws  were 
secured  by  the  dominant  legislative  class,  the  monied  class, 
for  its  own  immediate  benefit.  In  this  sense  these  laws, 
like  most  labor  laws,  were  class  legislation  and  nothing  else. 
But  there  did  develop  under  the  name  of  mercantilism, 
of  which  these  two  laws  were  precursors,  a  theory  of  state 
activity  which  entirely  neglected  the  interests  of  the  work- 
ingman.  Under  this  system  the  paternalistic  state  in  its 
endeavor  to  develop  itself  through  its  commerce  subordi- 
nated the  laborer  to  the  merchant  and  subjected  him  to 
minute  control  in  many  of  the  terms  of  his  employment. 
It  is,  of  course,  true  that  the  workingman  whom  this  legis- 
lation affected  had  just  emerged  from  the  status  of  serf- 
dom and  was  a  new  and  disturbing  factor  in  the  industrial 
life  of  the  time.  But  so  thorough  was  this  repressive  legis- 


12  THE  LABOR  LAW  OF  MARYLAND  [158 

lation  that  the  new,  free  laborer  was  hardly  in  a  better 
position  than  the  former  villein. 

It  was  against  this  system  that  Adam  Smith  and  Jeremy 
Bentham  wrote;  and  as  a  result  of  their  preachings  there 
ensued  the  period  of  laissez-faire  in  the  relation  of  the 
state  to  labor.  At  the  climax  of  this  individualistic  philoso- 
phy the  state  retired  almost  completely  from  the  regulation 
of  economic  affairs.  Competition  was  relied  upon  to  work 
the  salvation  of  society.  The  individual  laborer  was  made 
perfectly  free  to  bargain  for  his  own  terms  and  to  secure 
his  own  economic  betterment.  The  state  progressed 
through  the  progress  of  its  individual  citizens. 

The  period  of  laissez-faire  marked  a  real  and  substan- 
tial advance  for  the  workingman,  but  it  was  short-lived.  It 
was  not  any  inherent  fallacies  in  the  theory  which  caused 
its  modification — the  philosophy  of  individualism  has  never 
been  abandoned — but  rather  a  change  in  the  actual  condi- 
tions to  which  the  theory  had  to  be  applied.  Contempora- 
neously with  the  growth  of  laissez-faire  individualism  oc- 
curred that  stupendous  advance  in  industrialism  which  is 
usually  termed  the  Industrial  Revolution.  With  the  inven- 
tion of  steam-driven  machines  and  modern  means  of  trans- 
portation the  factory  system  of  manufacture  speedily  took 
the  place  of  the  small  shop  system.  A  single  employer 
began  to  employ  hundreds  and  then  thousands  of  laborers. 
The  laborer,  though  legally  and  theoretically  free  to  bar- 
gain with  the  employer  for  the  terms  of  his  employment, 
found  himself  practically  at  such  a  disadvantage  that  the 
employer  could  hire  him  almost  on  his  own  terms.  The 
labor  union  was  the  workingman's  answer  to  the  factory 
system,  but  it  has  not  yet  proved  adequate  in  itself.  The 
state  has,  therefore,  stepped  in  to  guarantee  to  the  laborer 
certain  terms  and  conditions  of  employment  which  have 
been  conceived  to  be  reasonable  and  necessary. 

This  is  the  present-day  status  of  labor  legislation.  The 
doctrine  of  laissez-faire  survives  in  so  far  as  the  state 
leaves  to  the  common  law  and  individual  action  all  that 


159]  INTRODUCTION  1 3 

these  instrumentalities  are  capable  of  handling.  Laissez- 
faire  is  abandoned  in  so  far  as  the  state,  recognizing  the 
inequality  of  the  bargaining  power  of  employer  and  em- 
ployee, regulates  as  seems  best  for  the  welfare  of  the  state 
certain  of  the  terms  of  the  bargain.  The  state  sacrifices 
theoretical  individual  liberty  for  what  is  considered  a  truer 
means  of  self-development.  The  state  in  its  endeavor  to 
offset  this  inequality  of  bargaining  power  has  returned  to 
some  of  the  functions  of  the  medieval  paternalistic  state; 
but  those  who  wish  to  make  the  distinction  between  the 
former  antagonistic  and  the  present  sympathetic  attitude  of 
the  state  to  labor  sometimes  term  the  present  state  mater- 
nalistic  rather  than  paternalistic  in  its  regulations.  To  a 
certain  degree  this  distinction  is  specious  and  more  will  be 
said  of  it  in  the  final  chapter  of  this  study.  It  is  sufficient 
to  say  here  that  the  solution  which  has  been  attained  in 
practical  legislation  is  hardly  a  final  remedy. 

In  the  United  States  there  is,  besides  political  theoriz- 
ing upon  the  relation  of  the  state  to  labor,  another  funda- 
mental to  be  considered.  Our  written  constitutions  en- 
forced by  powerful  courts  impose  a  legal  limitation  upon 
state  activity  as  well  as  a  philosophical  limitation.  While 
the  state  is  quiescent  the  constitution  is  unobtrusive;  but 
when  the  state  functions  in  enacting  laws  the  constitution 
exercises  a  tremendous  restraint  upon  state  action.  The 
whole  of  state  activity  in  the  United  States  affecting  the 
labor  problem  has  been  manifested  within  the  last  of  the 
periods  just  discussed,  that  of  laissez-faire  ameliorated  in 
favor  of  the  laborer.  All  of  this  social  legislation  comes  in 
conflict  with  the  "equal  protection  of  the  laws"  and  the 
"due  process  of  law"  clauses  of  the  Fourteenth  Amend- 
ment of  the  federal  constitution  or  similar  provisions  of  the 
state  constitutions.  Both  require  brief  discussion. 

The  essentials  of  "  equal  protection  of  the  laws  "  are  eas- 
ily stated.  Every  citizen  of  a  state  is  entitled  to  equal  treat- 
ment by  the  laws  of  that  jurisdiction  and  to  all  the  privi- 
leges extended  to  any  other  citizen  by  the  law.  Reasonable 


14  THE   LABOR  LAW   OF   MARYLAND  [l6O 

classification,  however,  is  permissible  if  exercised  on  ad- 
ministrative or  any  other  justifiable  grounds.  Legislative 
classifications  are  prima  facie  reasonable. 

The  "due  process  of  law"  clause  is  not  so  easily  ex- 
plained. Historically  it  is  traced  back  to  the  per  legem 
terrae  provision  of  Magna  Charta,  but  as  a  substantive 
provision  of  law  its  development  is  recent.  Strictly  con- 
ceived this  clause  might  have  been  construed  as  making 
perpetual  the  eighteenth  century  doctrines  of  laissez-faire 
and  natural  rights,  and  as  limiting  state  activity  to  the  nar- 
rowest bounds.  The  clause  luckily  never  received  so  nar- 
rowing an  interpretation,  but  was  merely  construed  as 
allowing  the  courts  to  inquire  whether  property  appropri- 
ated by  legislation  was  taken  for  a  legitimate  state  purpose. 
Early  in  their  interpretation  of  this  clause,  especially  with 
reference  to  social  legislation,  the  courts  evolved  the  police 
power  of  the  state  as  an  exception  to  the  prohibition  and 
through  this  exception  the  effect  of  the  prohibition  has  been 
much  curtailed.  It  is  indeed  more  profitable  to  consider 
the  cases  dealing  with  labor  legislation  under  the  Fourteenth 
Amendment  as  limiting  the  extent  of  the  police  power  than 
as  defining  due  process  of  law,  for  the  exercise  of  the  police 
power  is  due  process  of  law. 

Thus  viewed,  the  explanation  becomes  more  simple.  It 
is  still  impossible  to  define  and  limit  exactly  the  police 
power,  but  it  is  now  possible  to  give  rather  succinctly  the 
two  extreme  views  to  one  of  which  most  decisions  adhere. 
There  is,  on  the  one  hand,  the  strict  legalistic  view  that  the 
police  power  extends  only  to  the  protection  of  the  health, 
safety  and  morals  of  the  community ;  that  the  state  activity 
should  be  strictly  defined ;  that  none  but  the  most  moderate 
of  social  legislation  should  be  enacted.  The  Maryland 
Court  of  Appeals  leans  to  this  view,  although  it  is  not  en- 
tirely constant  in  its  principles.  The  other  view  is  that  the 
police  power  extends  also  to  the  furtherance  of  public  con- 
venience. As  put  by  Justice  Holmes,  "it  may  be  said  in 
a  general  way  that  the  police  power  extends  to  all  the  great 


l6l]  INTRODUCTION  15 

public  needs.  It  may  be  put  forth  in  aid  of  what  is  sanc- 
tioned by  usage,  or  held  by  the  prevailing  morality  or 
strong  and  preponderant  opinion  to  be  greatly  and  imme- 
diately necessary  to  the  public  welfare."1  This  is  the  view 
held  by  the  Supreme  Court  and  appears  to  exercise  practi- 
cally no  restraint  on  really  seriously  considered  legislation.2 
Having  these  fundamentals  in  view,  even  as  so  inade- 
quately outlined  in  this  chapter,  the  object  and  plan  of  this 
study  may  be  made  clear.  The  primary  purpose  has  been 
to  describe  and  analyze  all  of  the  law  of  Maryland  in  any 
way  concerning  labor.  In  order  better  to  understand  the 
law  of  Maryland,  I  have  usually  brought  it  into  contrast 
or  comparison  with  some  conceived  ideal  borrowed  some- 
times from  purely  theoretical  sources,  but  more  often  from 
the  law  of  other  communities,  generally  of  other  States  of 
the  Union  such  as  Massachusetts,  New  York  and  Wiscon- 
sin, but  when  necessary  going  to  England  and  Continental 
Europe  for  suggestions.  In  fulfilling  this  primary  purpose 
there  must  usually  be  some  incidental  consideration  of  the 
manner  in  which  Maryland  has  met  the  problems  which 
have  just  been  outlined.  This  discussion  of  political  theory 
will  be  kept  strictly  in  the  background  until  the  last  chap- 
ter, which  will  endeavor  to  lay  down  some  constructive 
principles.  The  plan  of  the  work  has  been  to  follow  as 
closely  as  possible  the  logical  development  of  state  activity. 
No  space  has  been  allotted  to  the  consideration  of  the  law 
of  the  labor  contract,  since  this  law  is  merely  an  adaptation 
of  ordinary  contract  law  and  contains  no  distinctive  feat- 
ures. The  study  begins  with  the  law  of  the  labor  union, 
which  has  been  almost  entirely  left  to  the  common  law. 
Then  follows  a  consideration  of  the  law  of  workmen's  com- 
pensation, which  marks  the  only  complete  abandonment  of 
any  principles  of  the  common  law  referring  to  labor.  The 
three  succeeding  chapters  deal  with  the  new  social  legis- 

1  Noble  State  Bank  v.  Haskell,  219  U.  S.  104. 

3  For  a  statement  of  the  author's  sympathy  with  this  view,  see  his 
article,  "  Imminent  Constitutional  Shams,"  in  the  Forum,  vol.  57, 
Jan.  1917,  pp.  91-98. 


1 6  THE  LABOR  LAW   OF   MARYLAND  [162 

lation,  demonstrating  how  far  the  laissez-faire  theory  has 
been  abandoned;  and  the  study  ends  with  chapters  on  the 
administrative  system  and  the  relation  of  the  state  to  labor. 
But  before  taking  up  the  law  itself  it  is  necessary  to  set 
forth  some  uninteresting,  but  necessary,  facts  about  Mary- 
land. 

Maryland  Conditions. — As  far  as  labor  law  is  concerned 
Maryland  will  be  found  to  be,  if  not  a  typical  American 
State — for  no  State  is  typical  when  legislation  is  in  question 
— at  least  a  mean  or  average  State.  Its  law  displays  none 
of  the  extremist  characteristics  of  the  experimentally  in- 
clined Western  and  Middle  Western  States,  nor  does  it  lag 
with  the  Southern  States  in  the  wake  of  social  legislation. 
It  follows  rather  closely  on  the  heels  of  New  York  and 
more  remotely  after  the  more  radical  Massachusetts.  Con- 
sidering its  geographical  position  Maryland,  with  its  some- 
what backward  labor  law,  may  be  judged  rather  leniently. 

The  State  is  usually  classed  as  one  of  the  Southern  States. 
Though  the  northernmost  of  these  States  and  outside  of  the 
Confederacy  in  the  Civil  War,  it  was  a  slave  State  and  had 
all  the  traditions  of  the  aristocratic,  non-industrial  South. 
Moreover  its  southern  neighbors,  Virginia  and  West  Vir- 
ginia, have  the  typical  Southern  labor  law,  perhaps  suffi- 
cient for  their  needs,  but  by  no  means  effective.  On  the 
other  hand,  Maryland  has  come  to  be  in  the  class  of  indus- 
trial States  and,  in  this  respect,  her  competitors  lie  to  the 
north  rather  than  to  the  south.  But,  here  also,  the  State 
is  restrained  rather  than  spurred  on  by  its  neighbors. 
Pennsylvania,  which  borders  the  whole  northern  boundary, 
has  until  recently  been  most  delinquent  in  its  labor  law  and 
many  of  the  odious  half  measures  in  the  Maryland  law 
have  been  caused  by  the  potential  competition  of  Pennsyl- 
vania's industries.  These  excuses  for  the  inferiority  of  the 
Maryland  law  call  up  an  explanation  of  another  cause  of 
Maryland's  backwardness.  Like  most  Southern  States, 
Maryland's  party  politics  are  at  a  low  ebb.  The  State 
does  not  seem  to  have  mastered  the  art  of  clean  politics  and 


163]  INTRODUCTION  \"J 

it  is  dominated  much  more  than  is  desirable  by  mediocre 
politicians.  Although  this  condition  does  not  perhaps  ac- 
count for  many  statutory  shortcomings,  its  effect  is  evi- 
dent in  the  administration  of  the  law. 

Aside  from  these  external  facts,  there  are  other  practi- 
cal difficulties  which  must  be  mastered  in  solving  by  legis- 
lation the  labor  problem.  The  population  of  Maryland  in 
1910  was  1,295,346,  about  evenly  divided  between  urban 
and  rural.  Of  the  urban  population,  however,  558,485 
people  are  collected  in  Baltimore  City,  which  is  the  only 
city  of  any  size  in  the  State.  There  are  besides  Baltimore 
three  other  cities  of  between  ten  and  twenty-five  thousand 
population  and  eleven  other  towns  which  are  classified  as 
urban.  Baltimore  is,  therefore,  practically  the  only  large 
industrial  center  in  the  State  and  in  it  alone  are  found 
many  of  the  social  problems  which  are  usually  the  occasion 
of  legislation.  Maryland,  furthermore,  is  divided  into  two 
unequal  parts  by  the  Chesapeake  Bay.  The  Eastern  Shore, 
with  a  population  of  200,161,  is  almost  entirely  rural  and 
the  only  industry  of  any  importance  is  canning,  which  for 
political  as  well  as  administrative  reasons  is  almost  unregu- 
lated. The  Western  Shore  may  again  be  divided  into  two 
sections,  the  Western  Shore  proper  and  Western  Maryland. 
In  the  first  of  these  is  Baltimore,  which  practically  domi- 
nates, the  industrial  life  of  the  section.  Western  Maryland 
lies  in  the  Appalachians  and  centers  around  Cumberland, 
the  second  largest  city  in  the  State.  Its  chief  industries  are 
coal-mining  and  transportation.  Western  Maryland  is  a 
narrow  strip  of  country,  and  it  is  chiefly  here  that  the  low 
standards  of  the  Pennsylvania  and  West  Virginia  labor 
laws  have  to  be  guarded  against.  Geographical  and  eco- 
nomic sectionalism  accounts  for  the  great  amount  of  local 
legislation  on  the  Maryland  statute  books  and  to  some  ex- 
tent for  the  lack  of  coordination  in  the  administrative 
system. 

In  1910  there  were  employed  in  gainful  occupations  a 


1 8  THE  LABOR  LAW  OF   MARYLAND  [164 

total  of  541,164  persons,  of  whom  410,884  were  male  and 
130,280  were  female,  comprising,  respectively,  81  per  cent 
and  25  per  cent  of  the  total  population  of  each  sex  above 
the  age  of  ten  years.  Their  occupational  distribution  was 
as  follows: 

Occupation  Number  Per  Cent 

Agriculture  171,100  21.6 

Manufacture    172,155  31.8 

Domestic  and  personal  service  / 78,820  14.6 

Trade   61,646  11.4 

Transportation    42,776  7.9 

Clerical    28,871  5.3 

Professional    23,474  4.3 

Public  service  '.  8,954  1.7 

Mining  7,368  1.4 


CHAPTER  II 
THE  LABOR  UNION 

The  Law  of  Union  Activities. — Historically  the  law  of 
labor  union  activities  was  the  first  evolved  by  the  state; 
evolved,  not  enacted,  for  most  of  it  is  judge-made  law. 
Logically  considered,  also,  the  law  of  union  activities  must 
be  accorded  first  place;  for,  granted  that  the  labor  union 
receives  favorable  treatment  from  the  state,  it  seems  easy 
to  demonstrate  that  hardly  any  other  state  activity  is  neces- 
sary. 

The  Maryland  labor  law  of  the  present  day  is  based  on 
and  grew  from  the  early  English  law,  and  hence  some  slight 
treatment  of  that  law  is  necessary.  The  beginnings  of  the 
English  law,  however,  are  somewhat  surrounded  in  mys- 
tery. It  seems  that  the  earliest  activities  of  the  union  were 
branded  as  criminal  conspiracy  at  the  common  law,  though 
it  is  by  no  means  certain  that  the  offense  of  criminal  con- 
spiracy was  not  the  creation  of  a  statute.  Be  this  as  it  may, 
before  labor  unions  as  such  came  into  prominence  statutes 
were  passed  early  in  the  eighteenth  century  forbidding  com- 
binations of  laborers  for  the  raising  of  wages  and  other 
purposes  and  making  such  combinations  criminal  conspira- 
cies. These  statutes  grew  in  severity  and  comprehensive- 
ness until  the  beginning  of  the  nineteenth  century.  There- 
after the  law  became  more  liberal.  The  cause  of  this  change 
was  the  union  itself.  Utterly  unsanctioned  and  potentially 
oppressed  in  its  most  beneficial  activities  by  the  law,  it  nev- 
ertheless continued  to  exist.  It  was  not  a  casual  phenome- 
non :  it  was  an  economic  growth,  necessary  to  and  justified 
by  industrial  conditions.  Slowly  and  often  surreptitiously 
it  grew,  but  grow  it  did  until,  in  the  atmosphere  of  greater 
political  liberty,  it  made  itself  felt  in  legislative  halls.  In 

19 


2O  THE   LABOR  LAW  OF   MARYLAND  [l66 

1875  the  ban  of  criminal  conspiracy  was  lifted  and  finally, 
in  1906,  the  union  was  granted  a  most  enviable  place  in 
English  law.1 

Maryland  in  1776  adopted,  with  the  other  twelve  States, 
the  English  law  of  union  activities  in  so  far  as  it  was  con- 
sonant with  American  ideas  and  ideals.  This  law  was  the 
harsh,  antagonistic  law  of  the  eighteenth  century  hardly 
modified  at  all  in  the  adoption.  Thus,  in  an  early  case,  the 
Maryland  Court  of  Appeals  sums  up  the  law  of  criminal 
conspiracy:  "An  indictment  will  lie  at  common  law — (i) 
for  a  conspiracy  to  do  an  act  not  illegal,  nor  punishable  if 
done  by  an  individual,  but  immoral  only;  (2)  for  a  con- 
spiracy to  do  an  act  neither  illegal  nor  immoral  in  an  indi- 
vidual, but  to  effect  a  purpose  which  has  a  tendency  to 
prejudice  the  public — for  a  conspiracy  (by  two  or  more) 
to  raise  their  wages,  either  of  whom  might  legally  have 
done  so;  (3)  for  a  conspiracy  to  extort  money  from  an- 
other, or  to  injure  his  reputation  by  means  not  indictable  if 
practised  by  an  individual,  as  by  verbal  defamation;  (4) 
for  a  conspiracy  to  cheat  and  defraud  a  third  person,  ac- 
complished by  means  of  an  act  which  would  not  in  law 
amount  to  an  indictable  cheat  if  effected  by  an  individual ; 
(5)  for  a  malicious  conspiracy  to  impoverish  or  ruin  a  third 
person  in  his  trade  or  profession ;  (6)  for  a  conspiracy  to 
defraud  a  third  person  by  means  of  an  act  not  per  se  un- 
lawful and  though  no  person  be  thereby  injured;  (7)  for 
a  bare  conspiracy  to  cheat  or  defraud  a  third  person,  though 
the  means  of  effecting  it  should  not  be  determined  on  at 
the  time."2  It  is  obvious  that,  either  under  the  third  clause 
declaring  indictable  a  conspiracy  to  raise  wages  or  under 
the  fifth  referring  to  a  conspiracy  "to  impoverish  or  ruin 
a  third  person  in  his  trade  or  profession,"  a  labor  union 
would  almost  surely  have  found  itself  running  counter  to 
the  law.  In  fact,  if  the  union  were  merely  formed  for  one 

1  For  a  complete  discussion  of  the  early  law  of  conspiracy  as 
applied  to  labor  unions,  see  J.  W.  Bryan,  English  Law  of  Conspiracy. 

2  State  v.  Buchanan,  5  H.  &  J.  317  (1821). 


I6/]  THE  LABOR   UNION  21 

of  these  purposes — and  it  must  be  remembered  that  these 
prohibitions  against  conspiracy  referred  to  the  indirect 
effects  as  well  as  to  the  direct  purposes  of  the  union — it 
would  be  absolutely  barred ;  for,  in  the  same  case,  the  court 
declared:  "A  conspiracy  is  a  substantive  offence  and  pun- 
ishable at  common  law,  though  nothing  be  done  in  execu- 
tion of  it."  It  seems,  indeed,  that  this  decision  was  entirely 
efficient,  for  no  cases  concerning  trade  unions  came  before 
the  Appeal  Court  under  this  decision.  But  it  must  not  be 
imagined  that  merely  because  no  cases  against  unions  came 
before  the  court  there  were  no  unions.  The  decision  was 
efficient  and  complete,  but  hardly  effective.  As  in  England, 
trade  unions  seem  to  have  flourished  even  under  the  shadow 
of  the  law  and  to  have  carried  on  trade  disputes,  perhaps 
not  legally,  but  extra-legally. 

It  was  probably  because  of  the  growing  strength  of  the 
unions,  especially  as  political  institutions,  that  the  legisla- 
ture of  1884  was  compelled  to  recognize  their  existence.  In 
that  year  two  bills  were  enacted  legalizing  labor  unions. 
The  first  declared  that  an  act  of  a  combination  formed  in 
"  furtherance  of  a  trade  dispute  between  employers  and 
workmen  shall  not  be  indictable  as  a  conspiracy,  if  such  act 
committed  by  one  person  would  not  be  punishable  as  an 
offense  (nothing  in  this  section  shall  affect  the  law  relat- 
ing to  riot,  unlawful  assembly,  breach  of  peace,  or  any 
offense  against  any  person  or  against  property)."3  The 
second  was  an  addition  to  the  incorporation  acts,  permit- 
ting the  incorporation  of  trade  unions  "to  promote  the 
well-being  of  their  every  day  life,  and  for  mutual  assistance 
in  securing  the  most  favorable  conditions  for  the  labor  of 
their  members."*  In  this  year,  then,  we  can  say,  the  labor 
union  entered  the  realm  of  law  in  Maryland.  In  this  year, 
also,  the  law  concerning  unionism  took  a  different  turn. 
Prior  to  this  the  unions  had  been  subject  to  the  law  of 

8  Laws  1884,  Ch.  266 ;  Code  1914,  Art.  27,  Sec.  40. 

4  Laws  1884,  Ch.  267;  Code  1904,  Art.  23,  Sec.  41.  Incorporation 
since  1908  takes  place  under  the  general  law  of  incorporation,  Laws 
1908,  Ch.  240,  Sees.  2-5;  Code  1911,  Art.  23,  Sees.  2-5. 


22  THE   LABOR  LAW   OF   MARYLAND  [l68 

criminal  conspiracy;  after  these  acts  the  employers  were 
able  to  combat  the  unions  in  court  merely  by  civil  suits  or 
injunctions.  Prior  to  this  year,  moreover,  no  cases  involv- 
ing unionism  came  before  the  Court  of  Appeals,  so  that  the 
Maryland  law,  in  contradistinction  to  the  English  law,  has 
practically  nothing  to  do  with  criminal  conspiracy. 

The  salient  principle  in  the  Maryland  law  of  labor  unions 
— and  indeed  in  all  American  law  on  this  subject — is  the 
right  of  the  individual  to  his  own  property  and,  what  is 
practically  identical  in  law,  the  right  to  freedom  of  contract. 
There  has  also  been  evolved  another  right,  sometimes  con- 
sidered a  property  right,  the  right  to  carry  on  one's  busi- 
ness or  to  work  at  one's  trade  free  from  outside  interfer- 
ence. This  right  is  indeed  a  recent  creation  of  the  courts, 
and,  to  a  certain  degree,  an  unfortunate  creation.  It  is 
broader  than  the  right  of  personal  freedom  and  was,  there- 
fore, useful  in  ruling  against  some  of  the  first  harsh,  but 
elusive,  activities  of  the  union;  but  there  are  two  sides  to 
this  right  and  the  unions  soon  came  to  assert  it  on  their 
side.  There  are  in  every  conflict  between  union  and  em- 
ployer two  conflicting  rights.  A  strike  is  called  for  an  in- 
crease in  wages  or  for  shorter  hours,  what  the  employees 
conceive  to  be  their  rights;  the  employer  forthwith  asserts 
that  his  freedom  of  contract  is  being  abridged.  A  labor 
union  stipulates  that  its  men  shall  work  only  in  a  "closed 
shop,"  and  the  discharged  non-union  man  sues  for  a  viola- 
tion of  his  right  to  work  as  he  will.  To  generalize  briefly 
in  advance,  we  shall  find  in  considering  strikes,  boycotts, 
closed  shops — in  short,  all  of  the  means  by  which  a  union 
makes  its  demands  effective — that  "honest  effort  to  better 
the  conditions  of  employment  by  the  members  of  a  labor 
union  is  lawful,"5  though  it  may  incidentally  interfere  with 
the  right  of  an  individual  to  work  on  such  terms  as  he  may 
see  fit.  If,  however,  the  aim  of  the  union  is  wilful  inter- 
ference with  the  individual,  though  the  union  may  thereby 
be  indirectly  benefited,  the  union  is  operating  contrary  to 

6Minasian  v.  Osborne,  210  Mass.  250,  96  N.  E.  1036  (1912). 


169]  THE   LABOR  UNION  2 3 

the  law.  Let  us  first,  however,  consider  in  some  detail  the 
law  relating  to  the  various  activities  of  the  unions. 

"The  right  to  organize  and  to  utilize  their  organization 
by  instituting  a  strike  is  an  exercise  of  the  common  law 
right  of  every  man  to  pursue  his  calling,  whether  of  labor 
or  business,  as  he  in  his  judgment  sees  fit"6  A  strike  per 
se  is  not  unlawful;  it  is  the  purpose7  or  the  means8  which 
renders  it  unlawful.  "  The  law  does  not  permit  either  em- 
ployer or  employee  to  use  force,  violence,  threats  of  force 
or  threats  of  violence,  intimidation  or  coercion,"9  so  that  it 
may  be  said  now  and  for  all  that  force  is  unlawful;  and, 
for  the  sake  of  brevity,  the  consideration  of  violence  may 
be  dismissed  from  the  following  discussion. 

The  leading  Maryland  case  on  labor  organizations  is  the 
case  of  My  Maryland  Lodge  v.  Adt,10  and  it  will  be  best 
to  quote  first  from  that  part  of  the  decision  relating  to 
strikes.  "  Employees  have  a  perfect  right,"  says  the  court, 
"  both  as  individuals  and  in  combination,  to  fix  a  price  upon 
their  labor,  and  to  refuse  to  work  unless  that  price  is  ob- 
tained. They  may  organize  to  improve  their  condition  and 
to  secure  better  wages.  They  may  even  use  persuasion  to 
have  others  join  their  organization.  They  have  an  unques- 
tionable right  to  present  their  cause  to  the  public  in  news- 
papers or  circulars  in  a  peaceable  way,  but  with  no  attempt 
at  coercion.  If  ruin  to  the  employer  results  from  their 
peaceable  assertion  of  these  rights,  it  is  a  damage  without 
remedy."  Laborers,  therefore,  may  strike  for  an  increase 
of  wages,  for  shorter  hours,  for  better  working  conditions, 
for  specified  methods  of  employment  or  of  pay.11  They 

6  Martin,  Modern  Law  of  Labor  Unions,  p.  36. 

7  Reynolds  v.  Davis,  198  Mass.  294,  84  N.  E.  457. 

8  My  Maryland  Lodge  v.  Adt,  100  Md.  283,  68  L.  R.  A.  152. 
» Ibid. 

« Ibid. 

11  It  has  even  been  held  in  a  federal  court  (Delaware,  L.  &  W. 
R.  R.  Co.  vs.  Switchmen's  Union,  158  Fed.  541)  that  workmen  may 
strike  for  such  purposes  even  though  it  be  in  violation  of  their 
service  contract.  What  the  court  very  probably  meant  was  that 
these  strikers  could  not  be  enjoined;  they  are  clearly  liable  for 
damages. 


24  THE   LABOR  LAW   OF   MARYLAND  [170 

may,  it  has  been  held,  even  seek  the  aid  of  their  fellow 
workers  in  another  establishment  to  join  with  them  in  a 
sympathetic  strike  if  the  employer  is  striving  to  circumvent 
the  efforts  of  the  strikers  by  having  his  work  done  in  brother 
employers'  shops.12  But  this  case,  although  well  considered 
and  precise,  must  be  confined  to  the  exact  point  involved; 
for  a  sympathetic  strike,  like  a  secondary  boycott,  usually 
brings  into  the  contest  an  uninterested  third  person  who,  if 
injured,  usually  has  a  cause  of  action  against  the  union. 
Where  there  is  such  a  community  of  interest  as  in  this  case, 
however,  a  sympathetic  strike  is  not  actionable.  Another 
danger  which  must  be  avoided  by  the  sympathetic  strike  as 
well  as  by  all  other  union  activities  is  the  possibility  that 
the  union  may  be  running  counter  to  the  contract  liabilities 
of  a  third  party,  for  "  a  man  who  induces  one  of  two  par- 
ties to  a  contract  to  break  it,  intending  thereby  to  injure  the 
other  or  obtain  a  benefit  for  himself,  does  the  other  an 
actionable  wrong."13  This  is  a  fundamental  rule  of  con- 
tract law  and  has  no  special  application  to  the  law  of  the 
labor  union :  it  is  mentioned  here  merely  because  of  the  num- 
ber of  times  the  union  has  felt  its  force.1* 

The  foregoing  conclusions  that  a  strike  is  a  legal  instru- 
ment of  the  labor  union  apply  only  when  the  disputes  are 
strictly  limited  to  the  two  parties  concerned,  the  strikers 
and  their  employer;  when  a  third  party  suffers  injury,  as 
was  intimated  in  discussing  the  sympathetic  strike,  the 
strike  stands  in  less  favor  with  the  courts.  Unfortunately 
it  is  a  rare  strike  which  does  not  directly  or  indirectly  affect 
some  third  person.  The  cause  of  this  can  readily  be  seen 
if  we  consider  the  problem  from  the  point  of  view  of  the 
unions.  The  strike  cannot  be  effective  if  the  employer  is 
able  to  fill  easily  the  places  of  the  strikers  with  non-union 

12  Iron  Moulders'  Union  v.  Allis-Chambers  Co.,  166  Fed.  45 ;  20 
L.  R.  A.  (N.  S.)  315- 

"Gore  v.  Condon,  87  Md.  368,  376. 

14  A  few  of  these  cases  only  are  here  cited :  Garst  v.  Charles,  187 
Mass.  144;  Folsom  v.  Lewis,  208  Mass.  336;  Iron  Moulders'  Union 
v.  Allis-Chambers  Co.,  166  Fed.  45. 


THE   LABOR   UNION  2$ 

men.  The  unions  strive  to  prevent  this  by  picketing  and  by 
making  the  union  monopolistic  as  to  that  particular  class  of 
workmen.  Again,  the  strike  will  not  attain  the  maximum 
efficiency  if  the  standard  which  is  obtained  by  the  union  is 
continually  undermined  by  the  cut-throat  competition  of 
non-union  men  in  the  same  shop.  The  unions  fight  against 
this  evil  with  the  instrument  of  the  closed  shop.  Again,  the 
strike  will  often  fail  entirely  if  other  employers  or  dealers 
trade  in  their  normal  manner  with  the  tabooed  employer. 
To  offset  this,  the  union  has  evolved  the  boycott,  or  more 
correctly  in  the  technical  economic  phrase,  the  secondary 
boycott.  But,  before  considering  any  of  these  more  ad- 
vanced forms  of  union  activity,  it  will  be  first  necessary  to 
consider  one  more  form  of  strike,  a  rather  more  advanced 
and  more  involved  form  of  this  particular  activity  which 
might  be  called  a  cross  between  the  strike  and  the  closed 
shop.  It  is  a  strike,  not  to  procure  an  immediate  advantage, 
as,  for  example,  a  raise  of  wages,  but  to  strengthen  the 
union  by  dictating  to  the  employer  certain  terms  of  employ- 
ment for  all  men  in  his  shop.  A  Maryland  case  will  illus- 
trate. 

In  Lucke  v.  Clothing  Cutters'  Assembly15  the  appellant, 
a  non-union  man,  had  had  permanent  employment  termin- 
able at  will  with  the  New  York  Clothing  House.  He  was 
objected  to  by  the  appellee,  who  notified  the  clothing  house 
that  they  objected  to  working  with  non-union  men.  Lucke 
applied  for  membership  in  the  union;  but,  because  of  the 
lack  of  employment  among  its  then  members,  the  appellee 
refused  him  membership.  Later  the  union  sent  notice  to 
the  employer  that,  if  Lucke  were  riot  discharged,  it  would 
notify  through  its  official  organ  all  labor  organizations  of 
the  city  that  "the  house  was  a  non-union  one."  Feeling 
that  it  was  threatened  with  a  boycott,  though  during  the 
trial  the  union  denied  that  this  was  its  intention,  the  New 
York  Clothing  House  discharged  the  appellant,  who  later 


"77  Md.  396;  19  L.  R.  A.  408  (1893). 


26  THE  LABOR   LAW   OF   MARYLAND  [l/2 

brought  suit  against  the  union  for  damages.  The  court  held 
that  Lucke  was  entitled  to  damages  since  the  union  had  in- 
terfered with  his  right  of  property  and  freedom  of  contract. 
This  interference  may  have  indirectly  benefited  the  union, 
but  it  wilfully  and  directly  injured  the  individual  in  one  of 
his  fundamental  rights;  and  the  court  said: 

"  It  is  not  necessary  that  such  interference  [of  the  union 
with  a  laboring  man's  privilege  of  seeking  an  honest  liveli- 
hood] should  have  been  malicious  in  its  character.  ...  In 
this  case  we  think  the  interference  of  the  appellee  was  in 
law  malicious  and  unquestionably  wrongful  .  .  .  and,  by  so 
doing,  it  [the  appellee]  has  invaded  legal  rights  of  the  ap- 
pellant for  which  an  action  properly  lies. 

"When  the  state  granted  its  generous  sanction  to  the 
formation  of  corporations  of  the  character  of  the  appellee 
(Code  1904,  Art.  23,  Sec.  37)  it  certainly  did  not  mean 
that  such  promotion  (of  the  well-being  of  their  every  day 
life  and  for  mutual  assistance  in  securing  the  most  favor- 
able conditions  for  the  labor  of  their  members)  was  to  be 
secured  by  making  war  upon  the  non-union  laboring  man, 
or  by  any  legal  interference  with  his  rights  and  privileges. 
The  powers  with  which  this  class  of  corporations  are 
clothed  are  of  a  peculiar  character,  and  should  be  used  with 
prudence,  moderation  and  wisdom,  so  that  labor  in  its  or- 
ganized form  shall  not  become  an  instrument  of  wrong  and 
injustice  to  those  who,  in  the  same  avenue  of  life,  and  some- 
times under  less  favorable  circumstances,  are  striving  to 
provide  the  means  by  which  they  can  maintain  themselves 
and  their  families." 

To  understand  more  thoroughly  the  significance  of  this 
case  let  us  look  at  one  apparently  opposed  to  it,  that  of 
Pickett  v.  Walsh,16  in  which  was  held  legal  a  strike  to  en- 
force an  agreement  between  a  bricklayers'  union  and  a  con- 
tractor, by  which  the  union  agreed  to  work  for  the  contrac- 
tor if  he  would  employ  its  members  to  perform  some  tasks 

« 192  Mass.  572;  78  N.  E.  753;  6  L.  R.  A.  (N.  S.)  1067  (1907). 


173]  THE  LABOR  UNION  27 

closely  allied  to,  but  less  skilled  than  bricklaying.  The 
court  differentiated  between  these  two  cases  on  the  ground 
that  the  strike  in  the  latter  case  was  on  a  matter  directly 
concerning  the  two  parties  to  it,  the  strikers  and  the  em- 
ployers, and  that  the  laborers  were  striving  directly  to  im- 
prove their  own  conditions.  This  distinction  seems  to  have 
been  generally  followed,17  but  in  discussing  this  question 
some  of  the  finest  legal  reasoning  has  been  used.  The 
tendency  seems  to  be  to  find  a  community  of  interest  among 
the  strikers  and  between  them  and  their  brother  unionists 
who  are  not  actively  engaged  in  the  strike,  but  for  whose 
benefit  the  strike  is  declared,  and,  on  the  whole,  the  trend 
seems  to  be  towards  holding  legal  strikes  aimed  at  securing 
these  competitive  advantages  for  union  laborers.  The  dis- 
tinction, however,  is  still  good  between  mediate  and  imme- 
diate quarrels  and  will  certainly  be  used  in  hard  cases  where 
justice  seems  to  demand  it.18 

If  the  tendency  has  been  towards  increasing  the  rights 
and  powers  of  trade  unions  in  securing  the  privileged  em- 
ployment of  its  own  members,  the  absolute  contrary  has 
been  true  with  respect  to  the  legality  of  picketing.  Labor 
unions,  in  fact,  have  suffered  to  a  great  degree  because  of 
of  injunctions  restraining  them  from  posting  members  on 
the  environs  of  the  place  of  strike  to  persuade  strike- 
breakers not  to  take  employment  in  the  hostile  shop  and 
to  obtain  information  as  to  the  employer's  activities.  Pick- 
eting, it  is  true,  was  far  from  being  such  a  milk-and-water 
affair  twenty-five  years  ago  as  it  is  now ;  it  was  in  this  ac- 
tivity, perhaps,  that  the  trade  unions  showed  their  ugliest 
side  and  incurred  the  ill-will  of  the  public.  This  popular 
estimate  seems  to  have  been  reflected  to  a  great  degree  in 
the  courts,  which,  beginning  by  merely  discountenancing 
picketing  that  was  contrary  to  public  order,  have  come  to 

17  E.  g.,  National  Fireproofing  Co.  v.  Mason  Builders'  Ass'n,  169 
Fed.  256,  26  L.  R.  A.  (N.  S.)  148;  and  Meur  v.  Speer,  32  L.  R.  A. 
(N.  S.)  792  (Ark.). 

18  For  a  fuller  discussion  see  note  in  6  L.  R.  A.  (N.  S.)  1067. 


28  THE  LABOR   LAW   OF   MARYLAND 

look  upon  almost  all  picketing  as  enjoinable,  if  not  abso- 
lutely criminal. 

A  general  declaration  of  the  law  was  given  in  the  case  of 
My  Maryland  Lodge  v.  Adt:18  "They  (the  union  laborers) 
may  even  use  persuasion  to  have  others  join  their  organiza- 
tion.20 They  have  an  unquestionable  right  to  present  their 
cause  to  the  public  in  newspapers  or  circulars  in  a  peace- 
able way.  .  .  .  But  the  law  does  not  permit  either  employer 
or  employee  to  use  force,  violence,  threats  of  force  or 
threats  of  violence,  intimidation  or  coercion."  The  trouble- 
some question  has  been,  what  is  intimidation  and  coercion? 
Thus  mere  argument,  where  the  odds  were  four  or  five  to 
one  in  favor  of  the  arguers,  has  been  said  to  constitute  un- 
lawful intimidation.21  Peaceful  picketing,  which  inci- 
dentally interfered  with  customers  patronizing  the  picketed 
shop,  has  been  enjoined.22  A  fair  statement  of  the  law  is 
contained  in  the  following:  "The  very  fact  of  establishing 
a  picket  line  is  evidence  of  an  intention  to  annoy,  embar- 
rass and  intimidate,  whether  physical  violence  is  resorted 
to  or  not.  There  have  been  a  few  cases  where  it  was  held 
that  picketing  by  a  labor  union  is  not  unnecessarily  unlaw- 
ful if  the  pickets  are  peaceful  and  well  behaved ;  but,  if  the 
watching  and  besetting  of  the  workmen  is  carried  to  such 
a  length  as  to  constitute  an  annoyance  to  them  or  their  em- 
ployed, it  becomes  unlawful.  ...  To  picket  .  .  .  was  in 
itself  an  act  of  intimidation  and  an  unwarrantable  interfer- 
ence with  the  employer's  rights."  Even  if  pickets  are  not 
guilty  of  intimidation,  "  the  complainants  are  entitled  to  pro- 
tection."23 The  Maryland  law  would  seem  to  go  quite  as 
far  as  this  Illinois  case,  for,  in  spite  of  the  rather  liberal 
language  just  quoted  from  the  Adt  case,  the  court  in  that 

19 100  Md.  283;  68  L.  R.  A.  752. 

20  See,  however,  Hitchman  Coal  &  Coke  Co.  v.  Mitchell  et  al.,  38 
Sup.  Ct.  65  (1917). 

21  Allis-Chambers  Co.  v.  Iron  Moulders'  Union,  150  Fed.  155. 

22  Foster  v.  Retail  Clerks'  Intern'tl  Protective  Ass'n,  78  N.  Y.  S. 
860. 

23  Barnes  v.  Chicago  Typographical  Union,  232  111.  421 ;  14  L.  R. 
A.  (N.  S.)  1018. 


1/5]  THE  LABOR   UNION  29 

case  upheld  an  injunction  which  practically  forbade  all 
picketing,  even  for  purposes  of  information  only.  It  would 
then  seem  that  picketing  has  been  in  law  practically  plucked 
of  its  stings :  picketing  can  perhaps  be  safely  used  only  as 
a  means  of  procuring  information.  This  would  indeed  be 
a  hard  blow  at  unionism  if  it  were  not  for  the  fact  that  an 
employer  will  not  usually  combat  in  the  courts  peaceful 
picketing  unless  it  is  used  in  conjunction  with  an  unlawful 
strike  or  boycott.  As  a  practical  matter  it  may  then  be  said 
that  peaceful  picketing  as  an  adjunct  of  any  other  lawful 
activity  of  a  union  is  not  likely  to  lead  to  any  action  at  law. 
If  used  in  its  really  civilized  form  this  most  powerful 
weapon  of  struggling  unionism  may  be  still  of  avail  in  in- 
dustrial disputes. 

Thus  far  we  have  been  considering  the  union  mainly  as 
a  body  of  workingmen ;  it  has  another  aspect,  that  of  a 
body  of  consumers ;  and  it  is  upon  this  quality  of  its  mem- 
bership that  the  union  relies  in  the  activity  usually  known 
by  the  name  of  the  boycott.  In  its  conflict  with  the  em- 
ployer the  boycott  is  a  frequent  weapon  of  the  union.  In 
itself,  as  will  be  seen,  it  is  not  a  very  efficient  weapon ;  but 
in  conjunction  with  the  strike,  with  which  indeed  it  is  gen- 
erally used,  it  often  enables  the  union  to  achieve  what  an 
unaided  strike  might  not  have  attained.  There  are  two  de- 
grees of  the  boycott,  primary  and  secondary ;  but  the  courts 
do  not  seem  to  observe  the  distinction,  some  including  the 
two  classes  under  one  head,  others  limiting  the  two  classes 
at  entirely  different  points,  and  a  great  number  having  ref- 
erence to  the  second  class  alone  when  they  speak  of  the  boy- 
cott. The  primary  boycott  is  the  act  of  a  combination  of 
individuals  who  agree  among  themselves  not  to  patronize  a 
certain  dealer.  The  secondary  boycott  is  the  act  of  a  com- 
bination which  tries  to  economically  outlaw  a  certain  dealer 
by  intimidating  third  parties,  either  by  strike  or  boycott,  to 
prevent  them  from  patronizing  this  dealer.  Assuming  the 
object  of  the  boycott  to  be  legal,  the  primary  boycott  is  gen- 


3O  THE  LABOR  LAW   OF   MARYLAND  [l?6 

erally  a  legal  activity  of  the  union,  whereas  the  secondary 
boycott  is  quite  as  generally  deemed  illegal. 

In  Maryland  we  have  a  leading  case  on  this  subject,  and 
it  may  be  well  to  consider  it  specifically.  The  case,  My 
Maryland  Lodge  v.  Adt,24  is  one  of  secondary  boycott,  but 
the  court  laid  down  some  additional  law  of  utmost  impor- 
tance. Adt,  upon  refusing  an  increase  in  wages,  had  been 
struck  against.  Further,  the  union  sent  circulars  to  the 
brewers  who  were  in  the  habit  of  contracting  with  Adt  for 
machinery  asking  them  to  boycott  Adt  on  the  ground  that 
he  no  longer  had  a  union  shop.  Upon  failure  of  the  brew- 
ers to  meet  this  request,  the  union  circulated  "unfair" 
broadsides  against  them;  and  in  self  defense  the  brewers 
were  compelled  to  withdraw  their  patronage  from  Adt, 
whose  business  was  thereby  practically  ruined.  On  these 
facts  the  Court  of  Appeals  upheld  an  injunction  against  the 
union,  and  declared  such  methods  of  warfare  manifestly 
unfair  and  actionable.  The  court  in  this  case  merely  held 
illegal  the  secondary  boycott;  but  some  of  its  language  is 
so  loose  that  it  may  be  possible  to  interpret  it  as  declaring 
all  boycotts  illegal,  especially  as  the  court  makes  no  dis- 
tinction between  the  two  classes  of  boycott.  It  is  submit- 
ted, however,  that  if  the  court  was  referring  to  the  primary 
boycott  per  se,  its  stand  is  hardly  justified. 

The  distinction,  indeed,  between  the  two  classes  of  boy- 
cott has,  as  was  intimated,  been  sustained  by  the  great 
weight  of  authority.28  An  individual  has  a  right  to  bestow 
his  patronage  where  he  wishes;  and  the  mere  fact  that  he 
combines  with  others  in  carrying  out  his  purpose  does  not 
make  the  act  prima  facie  actionable.  To  make  it  illegal 
there  must  be  in  the  object  or  means  of  the  primary  boy- 
cott some  malicious  purpose,  as  the  injury  of  another  with- 
out any  direct  benefit  to  those  engaged  in  the  boycott.  The 

24  100  Md.  238;  56  All.  721 ;  68  L.  R.  A.  752  (1005). 

25  See  American  Federation  of  Labor  v.  Buck's  Stove  &  Range 
Co.,  33  App.  D.  C.  83;  32  L.  R.  A.  (N.  S.)  748;  and  note  on  this 
case  in  L.  R.  A. 


177]  THE  LABOR  UNION  31 

primary  boycott  being  in  itself  lawful,  any  publication  in 
furtherance  thereof,  if  that  is  the  purpose  of  the  publi- 
cation and  no  intimidation  or  coercion  is  intended,  would 
also  be  lawful  ;26  but  here  again,  as  in  the  question  of  pick- 
eting, the  courts  are  prone  to  see  intimidation  in  any  pub- 
lication, with  the  result  that  the  unions  must  be  most  care- 
ful in  their  use  of  legally  recognized  weapons.  If,  then,  it 
is  dangerous  to  publish  unfair  lists  in  primary  boycotts,  it 
is  of  course  an  absolute  infringement  upon  the  rights  of 
another  to  publish  such  a  list  in  pursuance  of  a  secondary 
boycott. 

It  is  needless  and  would  be  indeed  useless  to  enter  here 
into  a  detailed  investigation  of  what  has  been  held  illegal 
boycott.  The  rule  seems  to  be  that  if  a  third  party  has 
been  drawn  into  the  controversy  between  the  two  contend- 
ing factions,  then  the  boycott  is  a  secondary  boycott  and 
he  against  whom  it  is  being  prosecuted  may  recover  for  his 
damages.27  This,  although  it  seems  to  be  well-settled  law, 
involves  an  inconsistency.  Take,  for  example,  the  Adt  case : 
employees  strike  for  increase  of  wages  and  in  pursuance  of 
that  strike  for  a  perfectly  lawful  purpose  institute  a  boy- 
cott against  the  employer.  In  the  Adt  case  there  was  some 
question  as  to  the  legality  of  the  means  used  to  enforce  the 
boycott,  but  that  does  not  seem  to  have  influenced  the  de- 
cision. Then,  granting  the  legality  of  the  strike,  why  should 
it  be  illegal  to  enlist  the  sympathies  of  third  persons  who 
deal  with  the  employer?  If  these  third  persons  are  injured, 

2«See  note  in  32  L.  R.  A.  (N.  S.)  1017;  and  cases  cited  there, 
mostly  New  York  cases. 

27 Thus  it  has  been  held  that  "a  combination  of  employees  to 
compel  their  employers,  by  threats  of  quitting  and  by  actually  quit- 
ting their  service,  to  withdraw  from  a  mutually  profitable  relation 
with  a  third  person  having  no  effect  on  the  character  or  reward  of 
the  employees'  services,  for  the  purpose  of  injuring  such  third  per- 
son, is  a  boycott  and  an  unlawful  conspiracy."  (Thomas  v.  Cinn. 
etc.  Ry.  Co.,  62  Fed.  803)  ;  and  that  it  was  illegal  for  a  union  to 
boycott  an  employer  of  non-union  labor  by  refusing  to  work  for 
another  employer  who  furnished  him  with  supplies.  [Burnham  v. 
Dowd,  104  N.  E.  841  (Mass.).]  There  are  innumerable  cases  on 
this  subject,  generally  decided  on  a  question  of  fact. 


32  THE  LABOR   LAW  OF   MARYLAND  [178 

are  coerced  into  the  boycott,  they  have  their  redress  in  the 
courts  against  the  union.  But  why  should  the  employer  be 
entitled  to  plead  in  a  controversy  between  himself  and  the 
union  the  injury  of  these  third  parties,  who  themselves  do 
not  complain?  The  employer,  it  is  true,  is  injured,  but  he 
is  injured  in  the  course  of  fair  competition  between  himself 
and  the  union,  and  it  is  damnum  absque  injuria.  If  we 
grant  that  a  strike  legally  pursued  is  justified  to  raise  wages, 
a  boycott  for  the  same  purpose,  as  long  as  no  third  person 
complains,  would  seem  equally  justifiable,  and  the  employer 
should  not  be  heard  to  voice  a  third  party's  injury  in  pro- 
tection of  himself. 

Perhaps  the  real  explanation  of  the  courts'  antagonism 
to  the  boycott  is  to  be  found  in  their  fear  of  its  potentiali- 
ties— for  it  is  one  of  the  most  efficient  weapons  of  the  union. 
But  if  this  explanation  is  true,  the  courts  are  certainly 
guilty  of  a  wrongful  invasion  of  the  legislative  domain  and 
the  explanation  is  merely  a  confession  of  this. 

Closely  connected  with  the  boycott  and  apparently  a  much 
more  effective  means  of  enforcing  the  boycott  is  the  fre- 
quently occurring  rule  of  a  labor  union  forbidding  its  mem- 
bers to  handle  non-union  material,  that  is,  material  pre- 
pared by  non-union  men.  It  has  been  held  that  the  union 
may  under  conditions  issue  such  a  rule.  Where  the  object 
of  a  labor  union  or  the  purpose  of  its  action  under  this  rule 
is  principally  to  injure  another  or  his  property,  the  agree- 
ment forming  the  union  is  unlawful;  but  where  the  pur- 
pose is  only  to  advance  the  interests  of  the  members  of  the 
union  the  union  is  not  illegal  and  such  rules  may  legally 
be  enforced.28  Here,  again,  the  distinction  crops  up  ber 
tween  the  "mutual  advantage"  of  the  laborers  and  the 
malicious  injury  of  another.  "So  long  as  the  motive  [of 
the  rule]  is  not  malicious,  the  object  not  unlawful  nor  op- 
pressive, and  the  means  neither  deceitful  nor  fraudulent, 

28  Bossert  v.  Brotherhood  of  Carpenters  and  Joiners  of  America, 
137  N.  Y.  321 ;  Gill  Engraving  Co.  v.  Doerr,  214  Fed.  in. 


179]  THE  LABOR  UNION  33 

the  result  is  not  a  [illegal]  conspiracy,  although  it  may 
necessarily  work  injury  to  other  persons."29 

The  distinction  between  this  rule  and  the  boycott  is  not 
easy  to  perceive  at  first  blush.  The  courts  have  distin- 
guished it  upon  the  ground  that  the  rule  was  laid  down 
before  any  difference  arose  between  the  employer  and  the 
union,  and  that  hence  it  might  impliedly  have  entered  into 
the  service  contract.  Moreover,  as  stated  above,  the  courts 
have  recognized  the  direct  interests  of  the  laborers  in  the 
rule;  and,  finally,  the  quarrels  have  been  directly  between 
the  employer  and  the  union,  the  boycotted  dealer  did  not 
enter  into  the  consideration.  This  method  of  boycotting  is 
naturally  only  applicable  in  well-organized  trades  with  a 
stable  membership,  and  the  older  and  more  stable  unions 
have  to  a  great  extent  made  use  of  it.  It  would  seem  one 
of  the  most  effective  instruments  that  the  unions  can  use; 
for,  not  being  tainted  with  the  ancient '  obloquy  of  trade 
unions,  the  courts  have  been  more  liberal  in  their  attitude 
toward  it. 

Precisely  corresponding  to  the  boycott,  but  issuing  from 
the  other  party  to  the  controversy,  is  the  blacklist.  It  is  a 
weapon  that  employers  have  been  fond  of  using  against  the 
strike.  As  such  it  would  seem  to  have  generally  been  held 
legal.  That  is,  if  the  employer  of  the  shop  which  is  the 
object  of  the  strike  should  distribute  to  his  brother  employ- 
ers, who  are  associated  with  him  in  trade  agreements,  a 
list  of  his  striking  employees  with  the  intention  that  these 
other  employers  should  refuse  the  strikers  employment  in 
their  shops,  the  courts  would  almost  certainly  hold  such  a 
blacklist  lawful.  But  it  is  practically  impossible  to  be  abso- 
lutely certain  how  far  the  courts  will  go  in  holding  any 
blacklist  lawful.  They  are  here  confronted  with  the  same 
conflict  that  has  been  evident  in  all  the  law  of  union  activi- 
ties, the  conflict  of  the  right  of  the  employers  to  carry  on 
their  business  as  they  see  fit  and  the  right  of  the  employees 

"National  Fireproofinj?  Co.  v.  Mason  Builders'  Ass'n,  169  Fed. 
256,  26  L.  R.  A.  (N.  S.)  148. 


34  THE   LABOR   LAW   OF   MARYLAND  [l8o 

to  the  free  use  of  their  laboring  powers.  As  was  said  in  a 
recent  Maryland  case,  "neither  [the  employer  nor  em- 
ployee] has  the  right  to  interfere,  without  cause,  with  the 
business  or  occupation  of  the  other."30  And  the  courts,  it 
would  seem,  are  more  opposed  to  the  combination  mani- 
festing itself  in  the  blacklist  than  they  are  to  the  combina- 
tions of  laborers  against  laborer.  We  have  seen  in  our  con- 
sideration of  strikes  directed  against  the  non-union  work- 
ingman,  how  eager  the  courts  are  to  protect  the  laborer 
against  the  combination,  but  they  have  been  somewhat  re- 
strained by  the  fact  that  the  two  competitors  are  in  the  same 
economic  position.  The  blacklist,  however,  represents  a 
combination  of  economically  strong  employers  functioning 
to  deprive  a  workman  of  his  only  means  of  livelihood.  It 
is  natural  that  the  courts  should  be  more  prone  to  condemn 
the  blacklist  than  a  combination  of  workingmen. 

The  blacklist,  nevertheless,  does  not  always  offend  the 
courts.  As  a  counter-weapon  to  the  strike,  as  has  been 
said,  the  blacklist  is  a  proper  thing.  On  the  other  hand,  if 
the  list  circulated  among  the  employers  is  tinged  with  slan- 
der, the  workingman  has  naturally  a  clear  right  of  action 
against  the  employers.  In  between  these  two  extremes,  it 
is  often  difficult  to  classify  a  blacklist.  "Any  malicious  in- 
terference with  the  business  or  occupation,"  as  our  Court 
of  Appeals  has  said,  "  if  followed  by  damage,  is  an  action- 
able wrong."31  This  is  a  safe  enough  guide  where  actual 
malice,  or  malice  in  fact,  is  evident  in  the  case,  as  it  was 
in  our  Maryland  case;  but  the  concept  of  malice  in  law, 
though  often  used  by  the  courts  in  their  reasoning  in  black- 
listing cases,  is  no  longer  of  much  practical  use  because  of 
its  extreme  elasticity.  It  would,  perhaps,  be  sufficiently 
correct  to  say  that  when  a  blacklist  is  used  against  striking 
employees  or  to  gain  a  legitimate  interest  of  the  employ- 
ers, it  is  legal,  but  when  it  is  used  merely  as  a  disciplinary 

30Willner  v.  Silverman,  109  Md.  341;  71  Atl.  963;  24  L.  R.  A. 
(N.  S.)  895  (1910). 
81  Ibid. 


l8l]  THE  LABOR   UNION  35 

measure  against  an  employee  and  to  attain  no  advantage 
for  the  employer,  it  is  an  actionable  tort  against  the  indi- 
vidual workingman.  That,  at  least,  is  the  Maryland  law. 

This  careful  regard  of  the  courts  for  the  welfare  of  the 
individual  is  not  directed  strictly  towards  the  unions,  and 
is,  therefore,  perhaps  not  appropriate  in  this  place;  but  so 
intimately  is  the  blacklist  related  as  a  counter  measure  to 
the  strike  and  boycott  that  the  unions  have  really  been 
much  strengthened  by  this  judicial  curtailment  of  the  em- 
ployer's powers.  It  seems,  in  most  cases,  that  the  decrees 
of  the  courts  have  been  adequate  enough  for  the  protection 
of  the  laborers,  but  the  public  has  not  been — or,  perhaps, 
it  is  more  correct  to  say,  the  unions  have  not  been — suf- 
ficiently satisfied  with  this  judicial  protection ;  and  in  many 
states  laws  have  been  passed  prohibiting  employers  from 
circulating  blacklists.  Innocent  information  is  not  prohib- 
ited, so  that  these  statutes  have  uniformly  been  held  con- 
stitutional. Maryland  has  no  such  statute,  but  from  the 
tendencies  of  the  court  in  the  case  of  Willner  v.  Silver- 
man32  such  a  statute  if  it  could  be  made  effective  would 
seem  desirable,  especially  from  the  union  standpoint. 

At  the  possible  risk  of  digression,  I  want  to  call  attention 
here  to  perhaps  the  greatest  encouragement  that  has  yet 
been  extended  to  unionism  by  legal  enactment.  With  no 
special  reference  at  present  to  Maryland  law,  it  is  yet  in- 
dicative of  a  tendency  in  the  law  which  may  at  some  future 
time  be  realized.  There  have  been  several  state  statutes 
and  one  federal  statute  relating  to  interstate  commerce 
which  have  declared  criminally  illegal  the  discharge  or 
threatened  discharge  of  employees  because  of  membership 
in  any  labor  organization.  Practically  all  of  these  statutes 
have  been  held  unconstitutional  as  depriving  the  employer 
of  the  right  of  contract  without  due  process  of  law ;  but  in 
the  Supreme  Court33  three  forcible  dissenting  opinions 

« Ibid. 

83  Adair  v.  U.  S.,  208  U.  S.  161 ;  52  L.  ed.  436 ;  and  see  note  in  this 
edition  on  State  cases ;  Coppage  v.  Kansas,  236  U.  S.  I ;  59  L.  ed.  441. 


36  THE   LABOR  LAW   OF   MARYLAND  [l82 

were  filed  against  this  position,  the  one  by  Justice  Holmes 
in  the  earlier  case  in  particular  being  most  suggestive  of 
future  modifications  of  the  severity  of  the  doctrine  under- 
lying the  majority  opinion. 

The  closed  shop  contract  is  the  highest  attainment  of 
trade  unionism.  It  is  still  a  method,  a  means  to  an  end, 
but  it  smacks  more  of  the  ultimate  desideratum  than  do 
any  of  the  other  activities  of  the  unions.  Once  the  closed 
shop  is  attained  in  an  industry,  collective  bargaining  has 
achieved  its  most  valuable  guarantee;  and  collective  bar- 
gaining is  a  primary  goal  of  unionism.  Unions,  according 
to  their  advocates  and  publicists,  are  striving,  not  for  the 
elevation  of  the  workingman  above  his  rightful  economic 
condition,  but  for  the  absolute  equality  of  the  laborer  with 
the  capitalist  and  the  landlord  as  a  claimant  in  distribution. 
All  the  phenomena  of  unionism  which  we  have  considered 
are  indications  of  this  ambition — the  strike  and  boycott,  the 
weapons  of  the  militant,  struggling  union;  the  agreement 
against  non-union  material,  a  defense  of  the  victorious 
union;  and  the  closed  shop,  the  security  of  the  old  and 
firmly  established  union.  It  is  therefore  obvious  that  the 
law  of  the  closed  shop  agreement — more  ^of ten  an  agree- 
ment than  a  formal  contract — will  be  somewhat  different 
from  that  of  the  other  methods  of  unionism.  Yet,  in  study- 
ing the  agreement  against  non-union  materials  and  the 
strike  against  the  non-union  workingman,  a  foundation  has 
been  laid  down. 

The  law  seems  to  be  that  an  agreement  between  one  em- 
ployer and  a  labor  union  that  he  will  employ  only  such 
laborers,  members  of  that  union,  as  the  union  shall  specify 
is  completely  enforceable.  Equally  unenforceable  is  an 
agreement  on  the  same  point  between  all  the  branches  of 
a  labor  union  within  a  certain  territory  and  all  the  em- 
ployers of  that  trade  within  the  same  territory.84  Between 
these  two  extremes  lies  the  debatable  ground.  It  is  as- 
sumed, of  course,  in  this  discussion  that  the  benefit  of  the 

84  McCord  v.  Thompson-Starrett  Co.,  198  N.  Y.  587 ;  92  N.  E.  1090. 


183]  THE  LABOR  UNION  37 

agreement  is  material  to  the  two  parties  and  that  there  is  no 
malice.  The  law  as  to  this  has  been  sufficiently  threshed 
out.35  The  law,  then,  with  respect  to  the  closed  shop  agree- 
ment  is  precisely  that  of  the  common  law  of  contracts  in 
restraint  of  trade,  that  of  conspiracies  in  unreasonable  or 
indirect  restraint  of  trade.  Where  the  agreement  between 
the  employer  and  the  union  is  too  monopolistic  within  too 
comprehensive  a  territory — of  course  much  smaller  than  the 
unreasonable  district  in  trade  monopolies — the  agreement  is 
an  unreasonable  restraint  upon  the  individual's  freedom  of 
contract  and  the  competition  of  the  non-union  laborer  is 
too  completely  stifled.  This  is  the  opinion  of  the  courts.  In 
the  eyes  of  the  economist — and  the  argument  seems  sound 
— a  trade  union  with  complete  monopoly  of  the  labor  in  its 
district  is  the  acme  of  perfection  of  competition,  of  com- 
petition among  the  elements  of  production. 

The  courts  seem  to  have  been  led  into  this  distinction  as 
to  extent  of  monopoly  in  a  rather  haphazard  manner,  if 
not  absolutely  against  their  will.  The  law  of  the  closed 
shop  has  been  most  fully  developed  in  New  York.  In  the 
earliest  case36  the  court  held  invalid  a  contract  between  a 
brewers'  association  and  a  labor  union  providing  that  no 
employee  of  the  association  should  be  allowed  to  work  for 
longer  than  a  specified  time  without  becoming  a  member 
of  the  union.  In  the  second  case,37  after  several  appeals 
and  reversals,  the  court  held  valid  a  contract  between  an 
employer  and  a  labor  union  providing  for  an  absolutely 
closed  shop.  In  this  case  the  court  specifically  stated  that 
the  early  case  was  not  overruled.  The  critics  immediately 
emphasized  the  conflict.  The  only  way  of  resolving  the 
conflict  was  to  develop  the  distinction  between  the  single 
employer  in  the  enforceable  agreement  and  the  association 

35  Cases  concerning  the  closed  shop  in  which  this  point  is  devel- 
oped are:  Berry  v.  Donovan,  188  Mass.  353;  5  L.  R.  A.  (N.  S.)  899; 
Kissan  v.  U.  S.  Printing  Co.  of  Ohio,  199  N.  Y.  76;  92  N.  E.  214; 
Hoban  v.  Dempsey,  104  N.  E.  717  (Mass.). 

88  Curran  v.  Galen,  152  N.  Y.  33;  37  L.  R.  A.  802  (1807). 

87  Jacobs  v.  Cohen,  183  N.  Y.  207;  2  L.  R.  A.  (N.  S.)  292  (1905). 


38  THE  LABOR  LAW  OF   MARYLAND  [184 

in  the  unenforceable.  This  distinction  was  developed  in 
subsequent  cases,  and  has  been  accepted  as  the  rule  in  cases 
in  other  states.88  Naturally,  what  is  lawful  in  this  respect 
for  the  labor  unions  is  lawful  for  the  employers,  and  there 
are  several  cases  in  which  open  shop  agreements  between 
employers  aimed  directly  at  the  unions  have  been  held 
legal.39 

It  might  be  profitable  to  present  a  brief  and  concise 
resume  and  to  draw  some  conclusions  from  the  Maryland 
law  of  labor  combinations  before  proceeding  to  the  specific 
statutes  which  are  based  upon  or  closely  allied  to  the  exist- 
ence of  labor  unions.  Since  the  statute  of  1884  labor  or- 
ganizations are  not  per  se  conspiracies.  An  act  which  is 
lawful  for  an  individual  is  therefore  perfectly  lawful  for 
a  union  to  undertake,  with  the  one  possible  exception,  most 
apparent  in  the  law  of  picketing,  that  in  certain  circum- 
stances numbers  themselves  may  be  a  menace  to  the  peace 
of  society.  However,  there  is  growing  up  in  the  law  of 
torts  a  theory  which  is  finding  great  application  in  labor 
cases  that  an  act,  though  conducted  for  perfectly  legitimate 
ultimate  ends  and  in  a  perfectly  lawful  manner,  may  yet  be 
actionable  if  immediately  inspired  by  an  improper  motive. 
Thus  a  strike  lawfully  conducted  to  strengthen  the  union 
may  still  constitute  a  tort  against  a  non-union  man  if  its 
motive  is  to  secure  his  discharge.  On  this  proposition  of 
law  is  based  the  rule  that  the  activities  of  labor  organiza- 
tions must  have  the  direct  purpose  of  improving  the  wel- 
fare of  the  members  of  the  association,  and  may  only  inci- 
dentally, indirectly  and  perhaps  unsubstantially  affect  a 
third  uninterested  party. 

But  these  generalities  do  not  help  us  much  to  appreciate 
the  trend  of  the  Maryland  decisions.  The  law  of  the  union 
is  in  its  present  state  of  uncertainty  because  of  conflict  of 

88  Connors  v.  Connoly,  86  Conn.  641,  45  L.  R.  A.  564;  and  note  ;n 
L.  R.  A. 

88  Hitchman  Coal  &  Coke  Co.  y.  Mitchell,  172  Fed.  963 ;  Goldfield 
Consol.  Mines  Co.  v.  Goldfield  Miners'  Union,  159  Fed.  500. 


1 85]  THE  LABOR  UNION  39 

two  generalities :  "  improving  the  welfare  of  the  members  " 
and  the  indirectness  with  which  the  interest  of  a  third  party 
is  affected.  The  courts  until  very  recently  have  been  in- 
clined by  their  training,  by  their  leaning  in  the  direction  of 
the  individualistic  philosophy  of  freedom,  towards  protect- 
ing the  rights  of  the  third  party,  no  matter  how  incidentally 
they  may  be  infringed  upon.  It  is  fair  to  say  that  they  did 
not  truly  understand  the  significance  of  unionism,  the  at- 
tempt to  secure  economic  equality  by  strengthening  the  bar- 
gaining power  of  the  laborers.  Maryland  law,  of  which  the 
last  case  was  decided  in  1909,  is  still  in  this  stage.  In  the 
Lucke  case  the  court  recognized  no  rights  of  the  union  to 
secure  employment  for  its  own  members,  but  considered 
merely  the  technical  right  of  the  individual.  In  the  Adt 
case  the  court  might  have  justified  its  decision  on  certain 
forcible  methods  of  the  union,  but  it  contents  itself  with 
unconditionally  outlawing  the  boycott  no  matter  what  the 
actual  economic  conditions  may  be.  Precedent  is  still  su- 
preme. In  the  Willner  case,  the  last  word  on  the  subject, 
the  court  might  possibly  be  said  to  have  taken  subconscious 
cognizance  of  economic  forces,  but  in  reality  the  decision 
in  favor  of  the  unions  was  reached  by  purely  individualis- 
tic reasoning.  It  may  be  hoped  in  view  of  certain  tendencies 
manifesting  themselves  in  other  lines  of  decisions  that  the 
Court  of  Appeals  will  in  its  next  union  case  take  a  broader 
view  of  the  province  of  law,  but  as  the  decisions  now  stand, 
though  the  results  in  all  these  cases  are  perhaps  justifiable, 
the  law  is  not  in  a  satisfactory  condition  and  Maryland  does 
not  deserve  a  position  with  the  more  advanced  states. 

Statutes  Relating  to  Unionism. — The  union  label  is  now 
recognized  as  one  of  the  useful,  if  not  necessary,  instru- 
ments of  organized  labor.  The  law  on  the  subject  is  rather 
difficult  and  the  decisions  most  conflicting;  but  the  Mary- 
land legislature  of  1892  has  relieved  us  of  the  necessity  of 
anything  more  than  a  cursory  sketch  of  the  unwritten  law. 
In  the  earliest  cases  the  union  label  was  defended  by  its 
advocates  as  a  trade-mark.  The  majority  of  decisions,  how- 


4O  THE   LABOR   LAW   OF   MARYLAND  [l86 

ever,  held  that  inasmuch  as  the  union  is  not  the  owner, 
manufacturer  or  seller  of  goods  to  which  the  label  is  at- 
tached, the  label  is  not  a  valid  trade-mark  nor  entitled  to 
protection  or  registration  as  such.40  Rebuffed  by  the  com- 
mon law  courts,  the  unions  strove  in  equity  proceedings  to 
enjoin  the  counterfeiting  and  unauthorized  use  of  the  label. 
Here  they  were  more  successful,  the  courts  viewing  the 
label  as  union  property.  The  courts  declared  that  the  con- 
cept of  property  should  not  be  fixed,  but  progressive,  de- 
veloping with  the  growing  society.  Surely,  therefore,  the 
label  is  property.  Witness  the  reasoning  in  a  Maryland 
case  in  a  lower  court : 

"The  object  and  effect  of  this  label,  as  used  by  plaintiffs 
on  their  associates,  is  to  increase  the  value  of  their  labor. 
...  It  will  not  be  denied  that  every  freeman  has  a  prop- 
erty right  in  his  own  labor.  .  .  .  From  this  broad  principle 
it  is  easy  to  develop  the  particular  proposition,  that  an  asso- 
ciation of  men  who  combine  for  the  purpose  of  increasing, 
by  legitimate  means,  the  general  demand  for  their  common 
labor,  have  a  property  right  in  whatever  lawful  instrumen- 
tality they  can  succeed  in  creating  and  controlling  for  that 
purpose. 

"If  the  combination  for  that  purpose  be  legitimate,  and 
the  label  itself  as  used  be  a  lawful  instrumentality  and  con- 
tains no  fraudulent  misrepresentation,  the  label  is  entitled 
to  the  recognition  of  a  court  of  equity  as  a  property  right, 
and  any  fraudulent  imitation  of  it  will  be  suppressed."41 
The  reasoning  here  employed  is  valid  and  convincing,  but 
nevertheless  this  opinion  is  in  conflict  with  most  courts  of 
the  country  which  have  refused  to  view  the  label  as  prop- 
erty in  the  absence  of  statute. 

,  Not  satisfied  with  this  tendency  in  the  Maryland  law — 
for,  of  course,  it  was  not  authority  since  the  case  did  not 
reach  the  Court  of  Appeals — the  unions  caused  the  enact- 

40  See  Martin,  Law  of  Labor  Union,  pp.  423-429,  for  a  more  de- 
tailed discussion  with  references. 

41  Cigar   Makers'   Union   of   Balt'o.   v.   Link.    Baltimore   Circuit 
Court,  1886;  reported  in  29  L.  R.  A.  202,  note. 


187]  THE  LABOR  UNION  4! 

inent  of  the  law  referred  to  above,  legalizing  and  protect- 
ing union  labels.42  The  first  section  declares  that  "when- 
ever any  .  .  .  union  of  workingmen  have  adopted,  or  shall 
hereafter  adopt  for  their  protection  any  label  .  .  .  announc- 
ing that  goods  to  which  such  label  .  .  .  shall  be  attached, 
.were  manufactured  by  a  member  or  members  of  such  union, 
it  shall  not  be  lawful  for  any  person  or  corporation  to  coun- 
terfeit or  imitate  such  label;"  and  following  sections  de- 
clare such  counterfeiting  a  criminal  proceeding,  enjoinable 
by  courts  of  equity,  and  cause  for  damages.  Registration 
of  the  label  is  also  provided  for.  No  case  seems  to  have 
arisen  under  this  statute ;  but  in  other  states  similar  statutes 
have  been  attacked  as  class  legislation,  but  without  excep- 
tion they  have  been  upheld.43 

There  is,  moreover,  on  the  statute  books  a  law  which  was 
passed  in  the  interests  of,  if  not  as  a  direct  political  plum 
for,  the  labor  unions  which  is  absolutely  and  undeniably 
unconstitutional.  It  is  the  law44  which  directs  the  "public 
printer  "  to  affix  to  all  public  printing  the  label  of  the  Inter- 
national Typographical  Union.  Precisely  similar  ordinances 
and  acts  have  been  held  unconstitutional  in  many  Western 
States  as  in  clear  violation  of  the  guarantee  by  the  Four- 
teenth Amendment  to  the  federal  Constitution  of  the  secur- 
ity of  property  under  the  due  process  of  law  clause.45 
.  The  final  problem  which  the  state  has  to  solve  with  ref- 
erence to  unionism  may  under  certain  conditions  become 
the  most  important  of  all.  It  is  the  reconciliation  of  the 
two  quarrelling  factions  in  any  labor  dispute  or  the  pre- 
vention of  the  dispute  itself.  There  are  two  main  classes 
into  which  legislation  of  this  sort  falls,  arbitration  and  con- 
ciliation, and  each  of  these  is  again  sub-divided  into  com- 
pulsory and  voluntary  methods. 
,  In  arbitration  both  sides,  labor  and  capital,  appear  before 

42  Acts  1892,  Ch.  357;  Code  1912,  Art.  27,  Sees.  50-55. 

43  See  note  in  39  L.  R.  A.  (N.  S.)  1190. 

44  Code  1911,  Art.  78,  Sec.  9. 

48  See  Miller  v.  ties  Moines,  23  L.  R.  A.  (N.  S.)  815  (Iowa),  and 
note. 


42  THE   LABOR   LAW   OF   MARYLAND  [l88 

an  arbitral  board,  usually,  though  not  always,  composed  of 
a  representative  of  each  contestant  and  a  non-partisan  chair- 
man, and  present  their  case.  The  board  deliberates  and 
hands  down  a  binding  decision.  If  reference  to  an  arbitral 
.board  is  compelled  by  the  State,  the  arbitration  is  compul- 
sory ;  if  reference  to  the  board  is  dependent  upon  the  agree- 
ment of  the  parties  to  the  dispute,  the  arbitration  is  volun- 
tary. Purely  voluntary  arbitration  is  rarely  found  in  present 
day  statute  books,  for  it  has  been  found  that  state  activity 
is  entirely  unprofitable  in  this  method  of  industrial  peace. 
.Compulsory  arbitration  has  been  tried  in  Australia  with 
varying  results  in  the  different  states.  It  suffers  from  the 
.fact  that  there  is  no  settled  theory  of  wages  discovered  as 
yet  upon  which  the  board  can  render  its  decision,  which 
must  accordingly  be  a  compromise,  a  result  not  too  favor- 
able to  the  principle  of  collective  bargaining.  Compulsory 
arbitration  would  possibly  be  unconstitutional  in  the  United 
States." 

.  Midway  between  arbitration  and  conciliation  as  a  means 
of  industrial  peace  is  a  hybrid  form  of  endeavoring  to  force 
peace  by  an  impartial  investigation  of  the  dispute  and  a 
full  publication  of  the  results  of  the  investigation,  both 
facts  and  conclusions.  By  providing  publicity,  this  method 
seeks  to  inform  public  opinion  of  the  true  state  of  affairs, 
and  by  directing  it  against  one  contestant,  to  compel  this 
contestant  to  yield  in  the  controversy.  This  method  usually 
occurs  in  legislation  in  company  with  voluntary  arbitration 
or  conciliation  and  smacks  a  little  of  each  of  these.  It  dif- 
fers from  the  compulsory  methods  in  that  it  relies  upon 
the  force  of  public  opinion  rather  than  on  the  physical  sanc- 
tion of  the  State.  Properly  administered  it  should  be 
effective. 

Compulsory  conciliation,  or  perhaps  more  correctly  com- 
pulsory investigation,  is  a  logical  development  of  the 
method  of  publicity.  It  seeks  to  prevent  industrial  unrest 

48  See,  however,  Wilson  v.  New  (decided  March  17,  1917)  as  lend- 
ing some  credence  to  the  contrary  view. 


l8p]  THE  LABOR  UNION  43 

rather  than  to  reconcile  two  contending  parties.  As  suc- 
cessfully employed  in  Canada,  workmen  and  employers 
before  declaring  a  strike  or  lock-out  must  appear  before  a 
conciliation  board  and  state  their  case  in  full.  This  board 
then  gives  its  decision  and  award  which,  however,  is  not 
binding  upon  either  party:  the  strike  or  lock-out  may  be 
consummated  as  though  there  were  no  decision.  The  find- 
ings of  the  board  have,  however,  been  meanwhile  pub- 
lished, and  public  opinion  is  relied  upon  to  prevent  the 
party  to  whom  the  decision  was  adverse  from  carrying  out 
its  intent  to  strike  or  lock  out.  This  scheme  seems  the  one 
most  suited  to  an  American  State  and  its  success  in  Canada 
testifies  to  its  worth. 

The  Maryland  laws  belong  to  the  class  of  voluntary  arbi- 
tration laws  and  one  of  them  has  the  added  provision  for 
an  impartial  investigation.  The  first  law,47  passed  in  1878, 
although  it  does  not  explicitly  refer  to  strikes,  provides  that 
"  whenever  any  controversy  shall  arise  between  any  corpor- 
ation incorporated  by  this  State  in  which  the  State  may  be 
interested  as  a  stockholder  or  creditor,  and  any  person  in 
the  employment  of  such  corporation,  which,  in  the  opinion 
of  the  board  of  public  works,  shall  tend  to  impair  the  use- 
fulness or  prosperity  of  such  corporation,  the  board  of  pub- 
lic works  .  .  .  shall  have  the  right  to  propose  to  the  parties 
to  said  controversy  that  the  same  shall  be  settled  by  arbi- 
tration " ;  and,  upon  the  consent  of  the  parties  to  the  arbi- 
tration, the  board  is  given  the  power  to  make  a  conclusive 
award.  This  law  is  only  of  antiquarian  interest  and,  as  far 
as  I  have  been  able  to  ascertain,  has  never  been  made  use 
of  in  a  labor  dispute.  It  is  of  the  most  inadequate  type  of 
this  kind  of  legislation. 

The  present  law  was  first  enacted  in  1904,  but  was  radi- 
cally amended  by  an  addition  in  I9i6.48  The  early  law 
gave  to  the  then  Chief  of  the  Bureau  of  Statistics  and  In- 

47  Laws  1878,  Ch,  379;  Code  1912,  Art  7. 

48  Laws  1904,  Ch.  671;  Code  1911,  Art.  89,  Sees.  3-11,  as  amended 
by  Laws  1916,  Ch.  406. 


44  THE   LABOR   LAW   OF   MARYLAND  [190 

formation  power  to  mediate,  arbitrate  or  investigate. 
Though  still  on  the  books,  the  provisions  of  this  law  have 
been  repeated  in  a  form  so  much  more  efficient  in  the  1916 
amendment  that  the  early  law  should  be  practically  super- 
seded. No  description  of  this  amendment  could  be  more 
clear  or  concise  than  the  text  itself. 

"It  shall  be  the  duty  of  the  State  Board  of  Labor  and 
Statistics  to  do  all  in  its  power  to  promote  the  voluntary 
arbitration,  mediation  and  conciliation  of  controversies  and 
disputes  between  employers  and  employes,  and  to  avoid  re- 
sort to  lockouts,  boycotts,  blacklists,  discriminations  and 
legal  proceedings  in  or  arising  out  of  such  controversies  and 
disputes  and  matters  of  employment.  In  pursuance  of  this 
duty,  the  said  board  may,  whenever  it  deems  advisable,  but 
subject  to  the  approval  of  the  Governor,  appoint  boards  of 
arbitration  for  the  consideration  and  settlement  of  such  con- 
troversies and  disputes,  and  may  provide  for  the  necessary 
expenses  of  such  arbitration  boards^  and  for  such  reason- 
able compensation  to  the  members  serving  thereon  as  the 
said  board  may  deem  proper,  not  exceeding,  however,  the 
sum  of  five  dollars  per  day  for  each  member  for  each  day 
during  which  such  member  is  engaged  in  work  upon  said 
arbitration  boards.  The  said  board  shall  prescribe  rules  of 
procedure  for  such  arbitration  boards,  and  the  said  arbitra- 
tion boards  shall  have  the  power  to  conduct  investigations 
and  hold  hearings,  to  summon  witnesses,  and  enforce  their 
attendance  through  the  ordinary  processes  of  law  in  the 
cities  and  counties  in  which  such  arbitration  boards  may 
meet,  subject  to  all  the  penalties  for  non-attendance  to 
which  witnesses  in  ordinary  civil  cases  are  subject,  and  in 
like  manner  may  require  the  production  of  books,  docu- 
ments and  papers  and  may  administer  oaths,  all  to  the  same 
extent  that  such  powers  are  possessed  and  exercised  by  the 
civil  courts  of  the  State;  and  said  arbitration  boards  shall 
make,  report  and  publish  findings  for  the  settlement  of  such 
controversies  and  disputes.  The  said  Board  of  Labor  and 
Statistics  shall  itself  have  like  power  to  conduct  investiga- 


I  pi]  THE   LABOR   UNION  45 

tions  and  hold  hearings,  summon  and  enforce  the  attend- 
ance of  witnesses,  administer  oaths,  require  the  production 
of  books,  documents  and  papers,  and  make  and  publish  re- 
ports and  findings  with  respect  to  any  and  all  matters  cov- 
ered by  this  section.  Subject  to  the  approval  of  the  Gover- 
nor, the  board  may  appoint  and  designate  a  deputy,  and  fix 
his  compensation,  who  shall  be  known  as  the  chief  mediator, 
and  who,  together  with  any  assistants  who  may  be  assigned 
by  the  board,  shall  have  in  charge  the  execution  of  the  pro- 
visions of  this  section,  under  the  direction  and  supervision 
of  the  board.  The  chief  mediator  may  act  upon  any  board 
of  arbitration,  but  in  such  event  he  shall  receive  no  com- 
pensation therefor  in  addition  to  his  ordinary  salary."  This 
law,  providing  as  it  "does  for  arbitration,  and  if  that  fails 
for  investigation  and  publication  with  very  efficient  means 
of  administration,  is  about  as  good  a  law  as  could  be  hoped 
for.  It  might  be  argued,  and  the  author  does  believe,  that 
compulsory  conciliation  would  be  a  more  effective  means  of 
industrial  peace,  but  the  law  as  it  stands  is  adequate.  If  it 
fails  in  its  purpose,  it  will  be  because  of  the  inevitable  weak- 
ness of  a  law  depending  on  public  opinion  for  its  sanction 
or  because  of  a  slackness  in  its  administration. 


CHAPTER  III 
THE  WORKMEN'S  COMPENSATION  LAW 

History. — The  Workmen's  Compensation  Law  occupies  a 
peculiar  place  in  the  study  of  the  labor  law.  It  differs  from 
the  law  considered  in  the  last  chapter  in  that  it  is  the  result 
of  a  definite  policy  of  state  activity  and  is  not  a  growth  of 
the  common  law.  It  differs  from  the  statute  law,  which 
will  be  the  subject  of  the  following  chapters,  in  that  it  is 
not  an  addition  to,  but  an  amendment  of  the  common  law. 
It  is  the  only  instance  we  have  in  the  field  of  Maryland 
labor  law  of  a  deliberate  wholesale  repeal  of  a  whole  sec- 
tion of  common  law  principles  which  were  conceived  to  be 
antiquated  and  unsuited  to  modern  industrial  conditions, 
and  the  substitution  for  them  of  a  new  statutory  system  of 
law. 

Maryland's  experience  with  workmen's  compensation 
laws  has  been  peculiar  and  somewhat  disconcerting.  It  was 
the  first  State  in  America  to  adopt  this  now  almost  univer- 
sal social  legislation,  but  it  was  decidedly  not  in  the  van  in 
adopting  a  really  satisfactory  law,  if  indeed  the  present 
law  is  entirely  satisfactory.  Its  priority  in  the  field  is  per- 
haps explained  by  the  horribly  inequitable  degree  to  which 
its  law  of  master  and  servant,  especially  the  harsh  doctrines 
of  assumption  of  risk  and  fellow-servant  negligence,  had 
developed. 

The  first  act  of  IQO2,1 "  conceived  in  ignorance  and  quickly 
forgotten,"  was  an  act  to  create  a  Cooperative  Insurance 
Fund.  The  law  was  limited  in  scope,  applying  only  to 
"coal  or  clay  mining,  quarrying,  steam  or  street  railroads 
.  .  .  and  any  incorporated  town,  city  or  county  engaged  in 
the  work  of  constructing  any  sewer,  excavation  or  other 

1  Laws  1902,  Ch.  139. 

46' 


193]          THE  WORKMEN'S  COMPENSATION  LAW  47 

physical  structure,  or  the  contractors  of  any  such  town," 
etc.,  an  estimated  coverage  of  about  ten  thousand  employ- 
ees.2 The  act  was  what  may  be  called  a  pseudo-elective 
compensation  scheme,  which  will  be  treated  at  greater 
length  in  the  following  section.  It  provided  that  the  em- 
ployers covered  should  be  liable  for  "  death  or  injury  caused 
by  the  negligence  of  the  employer  or  by  that  of  any  servant 
or  employee  of  such  employer"  unless  they  contributed  to 
the  insurance  fund  which  was  provided  for  by  the  statute. 
Half  of  these  contributions,  the  amounts  of  which  were  set 
forth  in  the  act,  might  be  deducted  from  the  wages  of  the 
employees.  The  only  insurance  provided  was  a  benefit  of 
one  thousand  dollars  for  the  death  of  every  employee  oc- 
curring "in  the  course  of  employment  and  by  causes  aris- 
ing therein."  No  provision  was  made  for  compensation  for 
permanent  or  temporary  injury,  and  in  this  respect  the 
workman  seemed  worse  off  than  before  the  passage  of  the 
law.  The  only  principle  of  compensation  which  seems  to 
have  been  accepted  in  full  was  the  liability  of  the  employer 
for  the  faults  of  his  employees.  The  law  was  of  question- 
able value  as  a  piece  of  social  legislation ;  its  real  value  was 
as  an  opening  wedge  for  future  enactments. 

This  act  remained  in  force  for  nearly  two  years,  during 
which  time  it  seems  to  have  been  well  administered,  though 
only  five  death  benefits  were  paid  out  of  it.  The  fund  was 
protected  from  insolvency  by  the  mutual  insurance  feature 
which  was  borrowed  from  Germany — practically  the  only 
sound  feature  which  was  obtained  from  the  extensive  ex- 
perience of  European  countries.  In  1904,  however,  in  a 
case  in  the  Court  of  Common  Pleas  of  Baltimore  City3 — 
the  act  never  came  before  the  Court  of  Appeals — the  law 
was  held  unconstitutional,  not  as  abrogating  the  constitu- 
tional rights  of  the  employer,  as  we  would  generally  expect 
to-day,  but  as  denying  to  the  employee  a  jury  trial  when  he 

2  See  G.  E.  Barnett  in  16  Quarterly  Journal  of  Economics,  p.  591. 
8  Franklin  v.  United  Railways  and  Electric  Co.,  reported  in  the 
Daily  Record  for  April  29,  1904. 


48  THE   LABOR   LAW   OF   MARYLAND 

wished  to  recover  for  the  negligence  of  the  employer.  "  The 
act,"  said  the  court,  "  embraces  cases  where  the  death  had 
been  caused  by  the  negligence  of  the  employer,  cases  where 
there  would  have  been  clear  right  of  action  in  the  courts 
under  existing  law.  It  enacted  that  employers  who  had 
made  the  payments  provided  in  the  act  should  by  such  pay- 
ments be  exempted  from  further  liability.  The  effect  was 
...  to  take  away  from  citizens  a  legal  right  which  they 
had  theretofore  enjoyed,  and  which  could  be  enforced  by 
them  in  the  courts,  and  also  to  deny  them  a  right  to  have 
their  cases  heard  before  a  jury."  The  court  seems  plainly 
in  error  in  the  first  part  of  its  decision,  for  it  was  decided 
as  early  as  the  case  of  Munn  v.  Illinois4  that  "  a  person  has 
no  property,  no  vested  interest,  in  any  rule  of  common  law. 
.  .  .  Indeed,  the  great  office  of  statutes  is  to  remedy  defects 
in  the  common  law  as  they  are  developed,  and  to  adapt  it 
to  the  changes  of  time  and  circumstances."  As  to  the  mat- 
ter of  a  jury  trial  the  question  is  more  complex  and  diffi- 
cult. Suffice  it  to  say  that  jury  trial  is  not  abrogated  if 
the  act  is  a  just  exercise  of  the  police  power;  and,  more- 
over, most  courts  in  the  case  of  pseudo-elective  acts  have 
refused  to  take  cognizance  of  the  implied  coercion  in  these 
acts  and  have  decided  that  where  those  affected  have  con- 
sented to  be  governed  by  the  law  there  is  no  deprivation 
of  due  process.  That  is  to  say  that  where  parties  have  con- 
sented to  try  their  case  without  the  intervention  of  the  jury, 
even  though  there  is  insidious,  hidden  coercion  pressing 
upon  them,  there  is  no  infringement  of  their  right  to  a  jury 
trial.  Such  argument  is  of  little  value  and  is  perhaps  con- 
trary to  Maryland  precedent,  but  the  courts,  in  spite  of 
criticism,5  have  often  used  this  species  of  reasoning. 
,  In  1910  the  void  created  by  this  decision  was  filled  with 
a  new  cooperative  relief  fund,8  but  even  further  limited 

*94U.  S.  113-134- 

5  See  Freund,  Constitutional  Status  of  Workmen's  Compensation, 
in  a  American  Labor  Legislation  Review,  43  (1912).    In  the  present 
(1917)  Maryland  law  the  servant  has  reserved  to  him  the  right  of  a 
civil  suit  when  the  employer  is  negligent. 

6  Laws  1910,  Ch.  153,  as  amended  by  Laws  1912,  Ch.  445. 


195]          THE  WORKMEN'S  COMPENSATION  LAW  49 

this  time  to  clay  and  coal  mining  in  Alleghany  and  Garrett 
counties.  The  act  provided  a  compulsory,  cooperative  in- 
surance scheme;  but  the  constitutional  difficulty  caused  by 
the  earlier  decision  was  obviated  by  allowing  the  employee 
to  sue  in  the  courts  provided  he  renounced  all  and  had 
accepted  no  benefits  from  the  Relief  Fund.  Another  con- 
stitutional question  was  avoided  by  calling  the  contributions 
of  the  employers  and  employees  "taxes,"  thereby  resting 
the  compulsory  power  exercised  by  the  State  upon  its  tax- 
ing rather  than  upon  its  police  power.  The  advisability  of 
the  change  may,  however,  be  considered  doubtful — a  leap- 
ing from  the  frying  pan  into  the  fire,  for  here  the  constitu- 
tional provision  against  levying  a  tax  for  a  private  purpose 
stands  rather  obtrusively  in  the  way,  but  it  may  be  said  here 
that  such  a  tax  has  been  upheld  in  a  Western  court  as  ana- 
logous to  a  license  tax.7 

This  act,  in  spite  of  the  constitutional  change  of  face, 
was  quite  an  improvement  over  the  former  law  from  a 
social  viewpoint.  It  provided,  as  intimated,  for  a  fund 
equally  contributed  by  employer  and  employee — though  for 
administrative  purposes  the  employer  paid  the  whole  tax — 
which  was  put  into  the  hands  of  the  county  commissioners 
of  the  two  counties  to  administer.  The  insurance  for  "  in- 
juries sustained  in  the  discharge  of  duty"  and  for  death 
are  far  from  sufficient,  but  there  is  a  great  increase  over 
that  provided  in  the  original  act.  $1500  is  granted  to  de- 
pendents upon  the  death  of  the  wage  earner ;  total  disability 
entitles  the  injured  to  $750  plus  one  dollar  a  day,  excluding 
Sunday,  for  twenty-six  weeks,  about  $180  additional ;  par- 
tial disability  entitles  him  to  $375  with  the  same  addition ; 
and  temporary  disability  to  the  dollar  a  day  benefit  for 
twenty-six  weeks.  The  waiting  time  in  all  cases  is  one 
week.  Although  the  law  provides  for  the  payment  of  all 
benefits  in  lump  sums,  the  legislators  recognized  the  possi- 

7  See  State  ex  rel.  Davis-Smith  Co.  v.  Clausen  (Wash.),  117  Pac. 
HOI.  The  Maryland  law  was  upheld  in  analogy  to  this  case,  see  128 
Md.  564. 


5O  THE   LABOR   LAW   OF    MARYLAND  [196 

ble  evil  of  this  method  and  strove  to  mitigate  it  by  consti- 
tuting the  county  commissioners  a  judicial  board,  first,  to 
determine  who  were  "  dependents  "  and,  second,  to  appoint 
bonded  personal  representatives  to  administer  the  reliefs 
granted  to  the  beneficiaries.  This  law  seems  to  have  been 
successful,  and  its  effectiveness  was  only  terminated  by  the 
passage  of  the  present  general  compensation  act. 

Again  in  1912  there  was  introduced  before  the  legislature 
a  Workmen's  Compensation  bill,  this  time  general  and  com- 
pulsory in  character.  When  the  bill  finally  emerged,  how- 
ever, it  had  been  completely  emasculated  and  converted  into 
a  harmless,  inactive  elective  compensation  law.8  This  pro- 
vided that  it  should  "be  lawful  for  any  employer  to  make 
a  contract  in  writing  with  any  employee  whereby  the  parties 
may  agree  that  the  employee  shall  become  insured  against 
accident  occurring  in  the  course  of  employment  which  re- 
sults in  personal  injury  or  death,  in  accordance  with  the 
provisions  of  this  act ;  and  that  in  consideration  of  this  in- 
surance the  employer  shall  be  relieved  from  the  conse- 
quences of  acts  or  omissions  by  reason  of  which  he  would 
without  such  contract  become  liable."  Being  purely  elec- 
tive, no  constitutional  questions  could  arise  from  the  en- 
forcement of  this  act.  Moreover,  the  law  has  been  entirely 
inoperative  and  is  only  interesting  as  the  direct  forerunner 
of  the  present  law. 

The  act  of  1912  covered  all  injuries  "arising  out  of  and 
in  course  of  employment"  except  where  the  injury  "is  the 
result  of  the  employee's  intoxication,  or  wilful  and  deliber- 
ate act  or  deliberate  intention  to  produce  such  injury."  The 
dependents  are  defined  to  be  "widow,  widower,  father, 
mother,  son  or  daughter  "  unless  otherwise  provided.  Noth- 
ing is  said  with  regard  to  alien  dependents.  The  schedule 
of  benefits,  although  still  rather  meager,  is  again  an  im- 
provement over  the  1910  Act,  and  is  again  topped  by  the 
present  act.  It  provides  for  a  death  benefit  of  thrice  the 

8  Laws  1912,  Ch.  837. 


197]          THE  WORKMEN'S  COMPENSATION  LAW  51 

annual  wages,  but  not  less  than  one  thousand  dollars;  in 
case  of  total  disability  for  a  benefit  of  at  least  fifty  per  cent 
of  the  wages  during  disability;  and  in  case  of  partial  dis- 
ability for  the  difference  between  the  total  disability  benefit 
and  what  the  injured  man  can  earn.  The  waiting  time  is 
again  one  week.  The  administration  is  vested  in  the  par- 
ties to  the  contract,  but  the  insurance  commissioner  has  full 
powers  of  investigation.  In  case  of  any  dispute  as  to  award, 
a  board  of  arbitration  is  provided  for. 

These  three  early  laws  were  repealed  by  the  passage  of 
the  1914  Workmen's  Compensation  Law,9  which  embodied 
many  of  the  best  features  of  the  earlier  laws,  especially  of 
this  last  elective  Employers'  Liability  Law.  The  new  act, 
however,  is  such  an  advance  over  these  experiments  that  a 
comparison  between  them  is  hardly  profitable.  It  will  be 
better,  therefore,  carefully  to  examine  and  analyze  this  law 
as  a  piece  of  social  legislation  in  comparison  with  certain 
ideals  which  have  been  formulated  for  compensation 
schemes  and  in  comparison  with  the  various  compensation 
schemes  embodied  in  the  laws  of  other  states.  After  this 
study,  it  will  be  necessary  to  consider  the  legal  aspects  of 
the  act. 

The  Present  Law  as  Social  Legislation. — It  seems  hardly 
necessary  at  this  late  date  to  enter  upon  any  detailed  argu- 
ment with  reference  to  the  merits  and  demerits  of  work- 
ingmen's  compensation  laws.  It  is,  nevertheless,  almost 
impossible  to  begin  any  discussion  of  this  legislation  with- 
out at  least  some  short  summary  of  the  pros  and  cons  of 
the  question. 

.  The  objections  to  the  laws  are  based  upon  the  common 
law  individualistic  conceptions  of  responsibility.  An  indi- 
vidual, it  is  argued,  should  be  responsible  only  for  his  own 
fault  and  negligence.  By  the  common  law  the  employer 
must  supply  the  employee  with  a  reasonably  safe  place  to 
work  in,  reasonably  safe  materials  and  machines  to  work 

9  Laws  1914,  Ch.  800;  Code  1913,  Art.  101. 


52  THE  LABOR  LAW  OF   MARYLAND  [198 

with,  and  reasonably  competent  fellow-servants  to  help  him 
in  his  work.  If  the  employer  complies  with  his  duties  and 
the  employee  is  nevertheless  injured,  the  loss  must  lie  where 
it  falls,  for  on  entering  an  employment  the  employee  as- 
sumes the  risks  of  that  employment,  and  visualizing  the 
possibility  of  injury  demands  higher  wages  as  a  sort  of  in- 
surance. When  confronted  with  the  proposition  that  the 
average  workingman  is  by  nature  an  optimist  and  neglects 
or  is  unable  to  insure  himself,  the  individualist  shrugs  his 
shoulders  and  conveniently  washes  his  hands  of  the  improvi- 
dent laborer.  He  quite  as  conveniently  waves  aside  the  in- 
equality in  the  bargaining  power  of  the  two  factors,  and 
assumes  that  the  employee  is  as  capable  of  refusing  unde- 
sirable employment  as  the  employer  is  of  refusing  employ- 
ment to  the  too  pessimistic  employee.  The  common  law 
individualist,  however,  is  stronger  when  he  argues  against 
saddling  the  employer  with  the  burden  of  providing  com- 
pensation for  all  accidents  occurring  to  employees  arising 
out  of  their  employment  irrespective  of  cause.  This  posi- 
tion is  absolutely  invulnerable  unless  it  can  be  proved  that 
the  employer  is  in  a  position  to  shift  the  whole  cost  of  the 
compensation  to  the  trade  and  thence  to  society. 

The  arguments  for  compensation,  on  the  other  hand, 
attack  the  problem  most  successfully  from  the  opposite,  the 
social  point  of  view.  From  this  standpoint  the  indictment 
of  employer's  liability  is  complete.  Unfortunately,  we  have 
no  Maryland  statistics,  but  it  is  safe  to  assume  that  her  ex- 
perience is  not  materially  different  from  that  of  other  States. 
In  the  first  place,  an  enormous  majority  of  the  industrial 
accidents  under  the  common  law  system  of  reparation  go 
absolutely  uncompensated.  Out  of  a  total  of  694,212  in- 
juries cited  in  the  New  York  commissions'  report,  only 
88,841  or  12.78  per  cent  were  compensated;  and  even  the 
fact  that  this  total  included  minor  injuries,  at  the  most  fifty 
per  cent  of  all,  does  not  materially  vitiate  the  conclusion 
drawn.  Moreover,  when  recovered — and  the  delay  is  often 
great  and  serious — the  compensation  is  usually  most  inade- 


199]          THE  WORKMEN'S  COMPENSATION  LAW  53 

quate,  if  not  perchance  superfluously  generous.  "A  good 
deal  to  the  very  few  and  nothing  or  very  little  to  most 
seems  to  be  the  principle  upon  which  the  liability  system 
worked  itself  out."10 

The  common  law  doctrines  of  assumption  of  risk,  contrib- 
utory negligence  and  fellow  servant  negligence  have  also 
come  in  for  their  own  special  condemnation:  the  assump- 
tion of  risk  theory  on  the  grounds  explained  above;  the 
contributory  negligence  theory  as  being  inequitable  in 
thrusting  upon  the  employee  full  liability  for  partial  fault, 
in  its  essence  a  lazy  rule  of  expediency;  the  fellow-servant 
doctrine  as  being  totally  inadequate  in  this  day  of  enormous 
factories  and  multitudinous  coemployees,  many  of  them  in 
entirely  separated  departments.  Moreover,  the  hostility 
aroused  under  common  law  principles  between  the  laborer 
and  his  employer  by  the  consequent  law-suits  and  bicker- 
ings is  surely  not  conducive  to  economic  peace  and  mutual 
understanding.  Finally,  and  this  argument  being  expressed 
in  dollars  and  cents  has  always  been  most  potent  with  the 
layman,  the  cost  of  administration,  the  lawyers'  fees  and 
the  court  costs,  have  annually  mounted  to  intolerable  fig- 
ures. This  was  a  direct  burden  both  upon  society11  and 
upon  the  injured  workingman  who  could  ill  afford  the  in- 
creased load.  All  of  these  defects  of  the  liability  system 
worked  a  hardship  upon  the  laborer,  generally  causing  him 
to  lower  his  standard  of  living,  if  not  to  become  an  actual 
object  of  charity.  To  prevent  this,  to  provide  compensa- 
tion for  every  injury  when  most  needed,  to  save  lawyers' 
fees,  to  promote  amicable  relations  between  the  employer 

10  J.  M.  Rubinow,  Social  Insurance,  p.  94.    This  book  is  rich  in 
statistical  matter.    Another  valuable  piece  of  statistical  work  is  con- 
tained in  the  congressional  report  on  compensation,  in  S.  Doc.,  vol. 
12,  62d  Cong.  2d  sess. 

11  There  is  some  argument  that  the  cost  of  administration  of  the 
compensation  law,  the  salaries  of  the  commission  and  its  other  ex- 
penses, will  be  as  great  as,  if  not  greater  than,  the  saving  accom- 
plished by  the  diminution  of  court  work.    This  argument,  even  if 
true,  can  weigh  little ;  for  it  is  not  the  cost  of  government  which  the 
compensation  laws  are  striving  to  effect,  but  the  social  cost  of  inca- 
pacitated, degraded  workingmen. 


54  THE   LABOR   LAW   OF   MARYLAND  [2OO 

and  the  employee,  these  are  the  aims  of  compensation.  To 
put  upon  the  consuming  public  the  duty  of  preventing  pov- 
erty instead  of  mitigating  wretchedness. 

The  arguments  are  clearly  in  favor  of  compensation; 
yet  the  inevitable  lag  of  legislation,  the  opposition,  entirely 
explicable,  of  the  capitalist  class  to  any  social  legislation 
which  will  affect  their  pocketbooks, — and  all  social  legis- 
lation must  necessarily  affect  their  pocketbooks  in  the  first 
instance,  though  the  intention  is  that  part,  at  least,  of  the 
burden  shall  be  shifted, — the  technical  shortcomings  of  the 
average  state  legislature;  these  have  kept  Maryland  for 
twelve  years  with  insufficient  compensation  laws  on  her 
statute  books. 

The  Maryland  act  of  1914,  however,  provided  for  a  com- 
pulsory system  of  compensation  insurance  in  certain  enu- 
merated extra-hazardous  employments.12  The  legislature 
flatly  challenged  the  constitutional  obstacle  of  due  process 
of  law  by  making  the  law  absolutely  compulsory  for  those 
employments  to  which  it  applies.  This  system  of  absolute 
compulsion  is  in  complete  accord  with  theoretical  opinion, 
but  in  almost  as  complete  contrast  to  the  actual  perform- 
ances of  various  States.  Only  four  states  out  of  twenty- 
four,  that  is,  Maryland,  New  York,  Ohio  and  Washington, 
have  compulsory  schemes.  The  others  have  sought  to  ap- 
pease the  courts  with  what  I  have  denominated  in  this  dis- 
cussion pseudo-elective  schemes.  These  latter  laws  are 
purely  elective,  though  often  with  a  presumption  of  election 
unless  notice  to  the  contrary  be  given ;  but  those  employers 
who  fail  to  elect  are  penalized  by  being  deprived  of  the  de- 
fenses of  assumption  of  risk,  fellow-servant  fault  and  con- 
tributory negligence,  and  burdened  with  the  added  disad- 
vantage of  popular  disapprobation  in  the  jury  trial  which 
must  take  the  place  of  compensation  proceedings.  The  em- 
ployee who  does  not  elect  is  left  in  the  same  position  as  he 
was  before  the  passage  of  the  act.  That  is  to  say,  the  hw 

12  Sec.  32  as  amended  by  Laws  1916,  Ch.  597.  See  also  American 
Ice  Co.  v.  Fitzhugh,  128  Md.  382. 


2oi]          THE  WORKMEN'S  COMPENSATION  LAW  55 

states  in  effect  first  to  the  employer:  You  are  perfectly 
free  to  choose  whether  you  will  come  under  the  compensa- 
tion scheme  or  remain  under  liability  principles ;  but,  if  you 
do  not  choose  the  new  compensation,  you  will  be  deprived 
of  your  three  common  law  defenses  and  the  jury  will  hardly 
be  disposed  in  your  favor.  Then  to  the  employee:  You 
have  the  same  choice ;  but,  if  you  do  not  take  up  with  our 
plan,  expect  no  favors  from  us.  The  courts  see  no  coercion 
in  this.  The  end  attained  by  this  system  is  practically  the 
same  as  that  reached  by  the  compulsory  system,  but  in  a 
clumsy  manner.  The  pseudo-election  has  been  a  sop  to  the 
courts,  which  have  refused  to  see  any  deprivation  of  due 
process  to  him  who  has  chosen  to  be  so  governed.  The  sub- 
terfuge has  been  successful,  but  the  courts  have  opened 
themselves,  and  rightly,  to  the  charge  of  inconsistency,  a 
quality  which,  interesting  as  it  may  be, in  other  fields,  is 
deadly  to  the  law.13 

The  Maryland  law,  as  has  been  said,  enumerates  the 
extra-hazardous  employments  which  are  covered,  making 
provision,  however,  in  a  blanket  clause  for  all  hazardous  em- 
ployments not  specifically  enumerated.  The  presumption, 
therefore,  is  that  any  dangerous  occupation  is  covered  by 
the  act.  On  the  other  hand,  "  farm  laborers,  domestic  ser- 
vants, country  blacksmiths,  wheelwrights  and  similar  rural 
employments,  casual  employees,  and  any  employee  whose 
salary  exceeds  $2000  per  annum"  are  specifically  ex- 
cluded.1* Practically  the  same  exclusion  exists  in  all 
States,  sometimes  by  explicit  exclusion  as  in  Maryland,  as 
often  by  limiting  the  application  of  the  compensation  scheme 
to  those  establishments  employing  more  than  four  or  five 
workmen.  This  exclusion  is  usually  justified  upon  the 
grounds  of  administrative  expediency,  but  it  is  also  true 
that  the  conditions  in  these  employments  are  still  practically 
the  same  as  they  were  before  the  Industrial  Revolution  and 
therefore  do  not  so  forcibly  demand  an  amendment  of  the 

18  Freund,  2  American  Labor  Legislation  Review,  43. 
"  Sec.  63. 


56  THE  LABOR  LAW   OF   MARYLAND  [2O2 

law  of  that  period.  In  addition  to  the  enumerated  list  of 
employments,  the  Maryland  law  provides  a  joint  elective 
system  of  compensation  for  all  other  employments  in  the 
State.15  That  this  provision  will  be  often  elected  seems 
doubtful. 

The  provisions  for  compensation16  in  the  Maryland  law 
cannot  be  rated  as  high  as  can  the  general  scheme.  The 
increased  cost  of  casualty  insurance  to  the  employer  has 
been  such  a  deterrent  upon,  the  legislators  that  they  have 
failed  rather  completely  to  enact  wisely  and  sufficiently. 
The  sudden  increase  of  burden  upon  the  employer  which 
must  necessarily  accompany  compensation  has  indeed  been 
the  real  obstacle  in  the  path  of  these  laws ;  yet,  if  we  cor- 
rectly understand  the  theory  of  compensation,  this  increased 
cost  is  no  real  objection. 

It  has  been  long  ascertained  that  one  of  the  foremost 
causes  of  poverty  is  the  death  or  disability  of  the  wage 
earner  of  the  family.  Poverty  was  not  originally  looked 
upon  as  a  social  disease  and  the  natural  remedies  for  it  were 
individualistic  in  character.  The  supremely  moral  and 
provident  device  of  "  setting  aside  for  the  rainy  day  "  was 
the  panacea  for  all  poverty.  It  proved  hardly  a  feasible 
social  cure  for  families  stricken  by  an  industrial  accident. 
The  average  workingman  is  naturally  optimistic  and  rarely 
visualizes  the  risk  of  his  employment.  Cooperative  socie- 
ties, furnishing  social  inducements  as  well  as  fraternalistic 
benefits,  were  devised  by  the  master  minds  to  cure  to  some 
extent  this  insidious  evil.  By  distributing  the  risk,  these 
societies  offered  a  degree  of  security  at  a  low  rate.  The 
remedy,  however,  was  not  complete;  for  these  societies, 
which  developed  into  gilds  and  finally  into  the  modern  labor 
union,  naturally  did  not  include  the  entire  working  popula- 
tion. The  outsiders  still  possess,  of  course,  the  old  resource 
of  self -insurance,  "  putting  aside  for  the  rainy  day,"  as  well 
as  the  newer  idea  of  insurance  in  an  organized  insurance. 

18  Sec.  33. 

16  Sec.  36,  as  amended  by  Laws  1916,  Chs.  368,  597. 


203]  THE  WORKMEN'S  COMPENSATION  LAW  57 

company.  The  newer  plan,  it  would  seem,  is  no  more  prac- 
ticable than  the  older,  for  the  workingman  is  naturally  in- 
different to  insurance,  especially  at  the  high  rates  which  his 
accident  risk  would  generally  bear.  This  antipathy,  or  at 
least  apathy,  toward  insurance  is  overcome  in  the  case  of 
the  labor  union  by  the  added  fraternalistic  advantages  and 
by  the  attraction  furnished  by  the  increased  utility  of  the 
union  as  a  fighting  machine,  advantages  which  seem  from 
the  viewpoint  of  insurance  of  rather  doubtful  value  because 
of  the  decrease  in  the  security  of  the  insurance  funds.  But, 
accepting  cooperative  insurance  at  its  greatest  value,  society 
still  has  on  its  hands  those  poverty  stricken  families  whose 
uninsured  wage-earners  have  been  incapacitated  or  killed  by 
industrial  accidents  and  those  families,  no  less  numerous, 
which  have  suffered  a  serious  set-back  in  their  standard  of 
living  because  of  insufficient  insurance.  Viewed,  then,  as 
social  legislation  and  totally  excluding  from  consideration 
the  equities  of  the  matter,  compensation  laws,  providing 
funds  to  tide  over  all  accidents  and  to  support  the  depend- 
ents of  killed  workmen,  are  conceived  to  offset  and  to  fore- 
stall this  important  cause  of  poverty.  Society  is  to  foot  the 
bill  and  employers  are  expected  to  shift  the  burden  which 
is  primarily  placed  upon  them.  It  is  perfectly  possible  to 
argue,  though  it  is  doubtful  whether  the  employer  will  en- 
thusiastically agree  with  the  argument,  that  the  employer 
should  invite  a  large  increase  in  insurance  rates,  for  it  has 
often  been  demonstrated  that  the  producer  can  be  assured 
of  much  greater  success  in  shifting  large  increases  in  the 
cost  of  production  than  small  increments. 

Washington  is  the  only  State  in  the  Union,  however, 
which  has  interpreted  the  dictum  of  social  insurance  liter- 
ally. Her  compensation  law  provides  for  the  care  of  de- 
pendent widows  and  injured  workmen  on  the  same  plan  that 
poor  relief  would  be  granted,  though,  of  course,  on  a  more 
generous  scale.  Upon  death,  the  widow  is  to  receive  twenty 
dollars  a  month  for  life  or  until  she  marries,  with  five  dol- 
lars additional  up  to  thirty-five  dollars  for  each  child  under 


$8  THE   LABOR   LAW   OF   MARYLAND  [204 

sixteen.  For  total  disability,  the  injured  employee  receives 
twenty  dollars  a  month  if  unmarried,  twenty-five  if  mar- 
ried, and  five  dollars  additional  up  to  thirty-five  dollars  for 
each  child  under  sixteen.  The  compensation  lasts  during 
disability.  In  its  other  provisions  the  Washington  law  de- 
parts somewhat  from  this  principle;  but,  though  the  com- 
pensation is  somewhat  low,  what  has  been  set  forth  suffi- 
ciently illustrates  the  theory  of  social  insurance — the  pre- 
vention and  abolition  of  poverty — which  has  been  developed 
in  Washington. 

Most  of  the  States,  however,  have  met  the  problem  by 
providing  compensation  commensurate  with  the  previous 
earning  power  of  the  wage-earner.17  The  accidents  are 
divided  into  three  classes,  those  resulting  in  death,  in  total 
disability,  and  in  partial  disability;  and  a  different  rate  of 
compensation  is  provided  for  each.  The  tendency,  though 
unjustifiable  on  theoretical  grounds,  has  been  to  divide  the 
class  of  partial  disability  into  various  categories  and  assign 
a  definite  compensation  to  each  kind  of  injury.  The  just 
method  would  be  to  compensate  the  injury  by  a  payment 
proportionate  to  the  loss  of  earning  power,  but  the  categori- 
cal method  has  been  made  use  of  in  order  to  lend  certainty 
to  the  amount  and  cost  of  insurance.  The  table  on  the  next 
page  shows  Maryland's  standing  as  to  the  rate  of  compensa- 
tion in  comparison  with  other  industrial  States. 

Maryland,  it  is  evident,  ranks  low  compared  with  these 
other  selected  States.  In  the  matter  of  death  benefits  the 
comparison  is  most  favorable  to  Maryland,  but  this  is 
merely  because  the  other  States  are  equally  delinquent,  not 
because  Maryland  is  nearer  the  standard.  New  York  is 
the  only  State  which  recognizes  that  the  needs  of  a  widow 
with  children  are  greater  than  those  of  a  widow  without 
children.  Maryland  is  prodigal  towards  the  small  family 
of  dependents  and  penurious  toward  the  larger  one.  This 

17  Provision  is  made  in  Maryland  (Sec.  47)  as  in  some  other 
States  for  a  consideration  of  the  possibility  of  increase  of  earning 
power  when  the  injured  workman  is  a  youth. 


205] 


THE  WORKMEN  S   COMPENSATION   LAW 


59 


b 
.2 

S 

09 

J5 

"-  °  _>2 

9 

fex  4^   o 

fex  ^    S> 

*^  Si 

tun  ft)  *     *     •     j 

I 

nW  £   0 

>O    !*   rf 

«m  |    £ 

£52  * 

>0    £ 

3 

0  *^ 

o 

>0  £*  0 

•a  o  o  o  o  o 

•Q    >O  I/)  >O  <O  <O 

S 

10 

t—>  If) 

1 

'  —  .  —  > 

a 

sconsin 

ft)     00 

o  w 

s  s? 

**  I 

6-1 

"rt 
«o    •  m   ft) 

1 

J3 

|3    5    5   S 

°^  0   O   O   O   0 

i 

3  rt 

.8  5 

s  'II 

^O     H     M     M     N     M 

0         0 

^o      *o 

^~ 

"* 

M             M 

o 
to 

oo   CO 

•S  2  o 

J 

0 

2 

^     ft)    I 
cX«  fti   O 

m«  V    ' 

u  t<»  >o 

^  |"    "   *   " 

O 

>o  fe  o 

o       <o 

o  «o  ; 

«*»""«»? 

>o  o  o  >o  10  o 

d       " 

O   O» 

«O  O    N    f>  O 

«_£!^ 

*>£ 

W      CN     M     M     H 

•2 

if 

. 

.               ' 

o 

WO       Q 

KO  10     . 

£    «0§ 

.O    ft)  «       «       «       « 

>• 

6^  O   ** 

O^   H 

v»  "T1  *" 

6^  <u 

fi 

fc 

OHO. 

n  ,,  3 

>o  >o   " 

o  **»    ' 

^  «O  CO 

o 

^    O    M    IO  00  OO 
^  M    O  OO    M 

gi 

10 

W    CO  N    d    H 

M73 

o 

>o 

w 

09 

.   PI 

09 

1 

05    **f 

J4 

S3  .5  0 

^<! 

5 

Rxw   I 

K?   H     ^ 

•o  **  o 

Kp    ft)  *      *      *      • 

fc 

o  v  o 

O      '       ^ 

go  2  • 

0    ^ 

1 

o^ 

H 

O   Pi*** 

«o  o  o  o  10  o 

«O  O    «O  t»  O 

^_5^ 

M     C<     M     M     M 

J5 

if 

15 

/| 

rt 

a! 

wO  S3      • 

a 

>O  H  e» 

\o  ^   " 

2 

t/2 

O  re 

>0   0     ' 

f 

5? 

»0 

«o 

N 

** 

1-1 

eath 
To  widow  .  .  . 
To  children.  . 

Dtal  disability 
Limit  of  payn 
Limit  of  time 

irtial  disabilit] 
Limit  of  payn 
Limit  of  time 

11151 

Q 

H 

& 

M  ci  fo  *  «o 

*:  OT 

I" 

CTJ  -;e 
0,0. 

•I 

C-P 

.2-^ 
ts  '"^ 

"OT  SP 

*a0^ 

^«fe 
o-2! 

^D   <L>   Ot 

a  »i 

^^^ 

*+«  "^'e 
OMH  £ 
e'^  rt 
§-« 

•n   C 


S   C 


rt  o  "^ 

"0   .     <fl 

IL§ 

1-1 

SOJ 
>  <- 
"C  «  o 
w^!^ 

S  o.2 

<2c 
«.2  o 

J3       -^3 
^2  * 

^SS 

O    4> 

1^1 
.|«3  0 

£  « j> 

a-c  js 
teHH 


6O  THE  LABOR  LAW   OF   MARYLAND  [206 

is  clearly  unjustifiable  legislation.  Moreover,  this  law 
abruptly  discontinues  at  the  end  of  eight  years  the  stipend 
which  only  too  often  had  been  just  sufficient  to  support  the 
widow  or  widower.  This  is  hardly  socially  or  economically 
sound  unless  based  on  statistics  of  the  average  length  of  life 
of  a  widow  after  the  death  of  her  husband  or  unless  the 
Maryland  legislature  wished  by  enactment  to  spur  the 
widow  on  to  a  second  marriage. 

The  Maryland  provision  for  total  disability  is  entirely  in- 
adequate. An  injured,  incapacitated  workman  is,  on 
grounds  of  abstract  justice,  entitled  to  his  whole  salary  dur- 
ing incapacity.  This,  however,  is  an  extreme  and  perhaps 
an  inexpedient  position.  Some  reduction  has  to  be  made 
chiefly  to  prevent  malingering,  but  also  to  satisfy  the  prac- 
tical sense  of  the  community.  In  one  European  country, 
however,  eighty  per  cent  of  the  workingman's  former  earn- 
ing capacity  has  been  granted  and  found  expedient,  but  in 
America  sixty-six  and  two  thirds  per  cent  has  been  deemed 
sufficient.  Maryland  provides  for  only  fifty  per  cent.  More 
serious,  however,  is  the  limitation  of  even  this  compensation 
to  eight  years  unless  the  laborer  by  dying  precludes  the 
limitation  becoming  an  injustice.  There  can  be  no  justifi- 
cation for  thus  terminating  the  compensation.  These  laws 
are  framed  to  prevent  poverty,  not  to  postpone  it  for  eight 
years. 

The  provisions  for  partial  disability  are  perhaps  less 
justifiable  than  those  for  total  disability.  Compensation  for 
partial  disability  in  Maryland  is  divided,  as  intimated,  into 
two  classifications:  temporary  partial  and  permanent  par- 
tial disability,  and  the  latter  is  subdivided  into  smaller  cate- 
gories. The  division  is  entirely  useless  and  very  confusing. 
The  compensation  for  temporary  partial  disability  is  fifty 
per  cent  of  the  loss  of  earning  power  due  to  the  injury, 
the  total  compensation  not  to  exceed  $3500.  If,  however, 
the  same  injury — and  it  is  not  impossible  to  conceive  one-- 
should  be  classed  as  a  permanent  partial  disability  not  cov- 
ered by  the  special  schedule,  the  rate  of  compensation  is  the 


207]          THE  WORKMEN'S  COMPENSATION  LAW  6r 

same  as  that  just  given,  but  the  maximum  is  reduced  to 
three  thousand  dollars.  An  impasse,  it  seems  to  me.  The 
specified  schedule,  as  will  be  seen  from  the  table,  seeks  to 
put  a  special  price,  based  upon  fifty  per  cent  of  the  weekly 
wage,  upon  certain  enumerated  injuries.  As  was  said 
above,  these  schedules  are  justified  merely  as  an  insurance 
device;  as  a  social  preventive  they  are  unjustifiable.  Tfiey 
would  admit  that  a  man  is  incapacitated  by  the  loss  of  a 
member  and  needs  compensation.  However,  in  two  or  three 
years,  it  is  to  be  assumed  he  will  have  recovered  and  have 
completely  adjusted  himself  to  his  new  mode  of  working, 
being  able  to  earn  sufficient  to  support  himself  and  his  fam- 
ily at  a  standard  little  below  his  former  standard  of  living. 
It  is  absurd.  Can  a  machinist  who  has  lost  his  hand  earn 
nearly  what  he  has  been  accustomed  to  earn?  Is  a  struc- 
tural steel  worker  who  has  lost  a  leg  a. capable  workman? 
The  only  just  compensation  is  a  percentage  of  the  loss  of 
earning  power  during  the  disability ;  yet  no  American  State 
has  provided  unlimited  compensation.  Massachusetts  is  the 
most  exemplary,  for  besides  providing  a  compensation  of 
two-thirds  the  loss  of  earning  power  during  ten  years,  it 
recognizes  the  fact  that  the  injured  laborer  will  be  in  greater 
need  during  the  first  year  of  his  injury  by  providing  a  com- 
pensation of  two-thirds  his  wages  for  this  year,  after  which 
the  regular  compensation  runs.  In  this  section  more  than 
jn  any  other  the  Maryland  law  is  inadequate  and  in  need 
,of  amendment. 

Another  feature  of  the  law  which  must  be  considered  in 
connection  with  the  compensation  provisions  of  the  act  is 
£he  section  dealing  with  what  is  technically  known  as  the 
"waiting  period."21  In  order  to  prevent  malingering  and 
to  exclude  those  innumerable  minor  injuries  which  it  is  in- 
expedient to  compensate,  all  compensation  laws  specify  a 
period  before  which  no  payments  are  granted.  The  stand- 
ards adopted  in  this  study  specify  from  three  to  seven  days ; 

"Sees.  49  and  36  (i). 


62  THE   LABOR   LAW   OF   MARYLAND  [208 

but,  though  in  some  European  countries  the  shorter  time  is 
made  use  of,  the  prevailing  practice  in  the  United  States 
is  to  enforce  a  waiting  period  of  fourteen  days,  though  in 
a  few  States  it  is  only  seven  days.  The  Maryland  law  pro- 
vides for  a  waiting  period  of  fourteen  days  except  in  the 
case  of  total  disability  when  the  workman  waits  only  seven 
days.  During  this  waiting  period  the  only  outside  help 
provided  for  the  injured  employee  in  most  acts  is  medical 
and  surgical  aid.22  In  Maryland  the  employee  is  entitled  to 
this  aid  at  the  expense  of  the  employer  up  to  the  amount  of 
one  hundred  and  fifty  dollars,  so  that  it  may  continue  longer 
than  the  waiting  period  if  necessary.23 

In  most  States  the  compensation  provided  in  the  sections 
just  discussed  is  the  sole  remedy  of  the  workingman.  In 
Maryland,  however,  on  account  of  the  constitutional  diffi- 
culties previously  set  forth,  whether  sound  or  not,  it  is  pro- 
vided that  "if  the  injury  or  death  results  to  a  workman 
from  the  deliberate  intention  of  his  employer,  the  employee 
or  his  widow  .  .  .  may  have  a  cause  of  action  as  if  this 
Act  had  not  been  passed/'2*  Except  in  such  a  case  the  em- 
ployee or  his  dependents,25  upon  proper  notice  to  his  em- 
ployer26 and  upon  periodic  medical  examinations27  is  en- 
titled to  his  compensation  and  he  is  absolutely  forbidden  to 
surrender  this  right  by  any  contract.28 

22  It  is  sometimes  argued  against  the  long  waiting  period  that  the 
low  paid  laborer  may  be  forced  below  the  subsistence  line  in  the 
first  month  of  his  injury  and  never  again  be  able  to  pull  himself 
above  it.    E.  g.,  a  laborer,  with  a  family  of  four,  earning  twelve 
dollars  a  week,  is  injured.    His  total  compensation   for  the  first 
month  of  his  injury  will  be  just  equal  to  his  former  weekly  wage. 
The  argument  is  strong,  but  seems  outweighed  by  considerations  of 
expediency  and  of  penalizing  improvidence.  ' 

23  Sec.  37,  as  amended  by  Laws  1916,  Ch.  597. 
2*  Sec.  45- 

25  Non-resident  aliens  are  included.    Sec.  36,  as  amended  by  Laws 
1916,  Ch.  368. 
28  Sec.  38. 

27  Sec.  42. 

28  Sec.  53.    A  recent  decision  of  the  Massachusetts  Supreme  Cour'. 
has  stated  that  the  compensation  provided  in  the  act  does  not  relieve 
the  employer  from  liability  to  the  parents  of  a  minor  for  loss  of 
service.     (King  v.  Viscoloid  Co.,  106  N.  E.  988.)     It  seems  hardly 


209]          THE  WORKMEN'S  COMPENSATION  LAW  63 

The  compensation  is  paid  for  disability  or  death  "  result- 
ing from  an  accidental  personal  injury  .  .  .  arising  out  of 
and  in  the  course  of  employment  without  regard  to  fault 
as  a  cause  of  such  injury  "  and  "  such  disease  or  infection 
as  may  naturally  result  therefrom."  However,  "  where  the 
injury  is  occasioned  by  the  wilful  intention  of  the  injured 
employee  to  bring  about  the  injury  to  himself  or  another, 
or  where  the  injury  results  solely  from  the  intoxication  of 
the  injured  employee,"  no  compensation  is  recoverable.20 
This  or  a  similar  section  has  given  rise  in  every  State  to 
an  immense  amount  of  litigation,  but  it  will  not  be  neces- 
sary to  delay  longer  here  than  to  quote  the  definition 
adopted  by  the  Maryland  commission : 

"An  injury  is  received  in  the  course  of  employment 
when  it  comes  while  the  person  is  doing  the  duty  which 
he  is  employed  to  perform.  It  arises  out  of  the  employ- 
ment when  there  is  apparent  to  the  rational  mind,  upon  con- 
sideration of  all  circumstances,  a  causal  connection  between 
the  conditions  under  which  the  work  is  required  to  be  per- 
formed and  the  resulting  injury.  Under  this  test  if  the 
injury  can  be  seen  to  have  followed  as  a  natural  incident  of 
the  work,  and  to  have  been  contemplated  by  a  reasonable 
person  familiar  with  the  whole  situation  as  a  result  of  the 
exposure  occasioned  by  the  nature  of  the  employment,  then 
it  arises  out  of  employment.  But  it  excludes  an  injury 
which  cannot  fairly  be  traced  to  the  employment  as  a  con- 
possible  that  such  a  decision  could  occur  under  the  Maryland  law. 
The  Massachusetts  law  is  a  pseudo-elective  law  and  provides  only 
that  unless  the  employee  shall  have  given  contrary  notice,  he  will  be 
assumed  to  have  surrendered  his  rights  to  any  recovery  outside  the 
law.  This,  says  the  court,  does  not  abrogate  the  parents'  right  of 
recovery  for  it  is  a  "  rule  of  statutory  construction  that  an  existing 
common  law  right  of  action  is  not  to  be  taken  away  by  a  statute 
unless  by  direct  enactment  or  necessary  implication."  In  the  Mary- 
land act,  however,  it  is  provided  that  the  common  law  rule  "  that 
statutes  in  derogation  of  the  common  law  are  to  be  strictly  construed 
shall  have  no  application  to  this  act"  (Sec.  61)  ;  and,  moreover,  that 
payment  under  the  act  "  shall  be  in  lieu  of  any  and  all  rights  of 
action  whatsoever  against  any  person  whomsoever"  (Sec.  36). 

29  Sees.  14  and  63  (6) ,  as  amended  by  Laws  1916,  Ch.  593.  See 
also  American  Ice  Co.  v.  Fitzhugh,  128  Md.  382. 


64  THE  LABOR  LAW  OF   MARYLAND  [2IO 

tributing  proximate  cause  and  which  comes  from  a  hazard 
to  which  the  workman  would  have  been  equally  exposed 
apart  from  the  employment.  The  causative  danger  must 
Jae  peculiar  to  the  work  and  not  common  to  the  neighbor- 
hood. It  must  be  incidental  to  the  character  of  the  busi- 
ness and  not  independent  of  the  relation  of  master  and 
servant.  It  need  not  have  been  foreseen  or  expected,  but 
after  the  event  it  must  appear  to  have  had  its  origin  in  the 
risk  connected  with  the  employment,  and  to  have  flowed 
£rom  that  source  as  a  rational  consequence."30 

It  may  be  noted  here  that,  since  the  compensation  law 
does  not  cover  occupational  diseases,  Maryland  is  without 
any  legal  remedy  for  this  industrial  evil,  for  under  the  com- 
mon law  doctrines  it  would  be  practically  impossible  to  re- 
cover from  the  employer  in  the  courts.  The  legislative  prin- 
ciples upon  which  these  diseases  are  excluded  from  the 
operation  of  this  act  are  perhaps  sound,  but  some  provision 
^hould  be  made  in  a  separate  act  for  compensation  of  the 
incapacitated.  It  is  obvious  that  the  same  reasons  which 
demanded  the  passage  of  the  compensation  law,  the  social 
and  individual  effects  of  uncompensated  injuries,  as  loudly 
call  for  an  act  whereby  the  diseases  inevitable  to  the  occu- 
pation should  be  borne  by  the  occupation.  Practically  every 
European  country  has  a  law  of  this  kind,  but  the  acceptance 
of  the  principle  has  been  slow  in  this  country. 

The  provisions  of  the  law  which  have  been  considered 
are,  of  course,  those  most  important  to  the  laborer.  It  is, 
unfortunately,  this  part  of  the  Maryland  law  which  is  most 
deficient.  However,  a  law  is  not  a  law  until  it  is  adminis- 
tered, and  it  is,  therefore,  of  utmost  importance  to  the  bene- 
ficiary of  the  act  that  its  administration  be  efficient.  For- 
tunately, the  sections  of  the  Maryland  act  dealing  with  the 
administration  and  insurance  are  most  complete  and  most 
satisfactory. 

The  greatest  necessity,  after  once  establishing  the  true 
compensation  principle,  is  to  provide  some  method  of  guar- 

80  Claim  No.  224,  quoting  from  McNichol  v.  Emp.  Lia.  Ass.  Co., 
215  Mass.  497. 


2ii]          THE  WORKMEN'S  COMPENSATION  LAW  65 

anteeing  the  payments  to  the  injured  employee.  It  is  easy 
to  conceive  of  a  compensation  law  totally  invalidated  by  the 
inability  of  the  employers  to  make  sufficient  payments  after 
the  accident  because  of  insolvency  or  other  unforeseen  dif- 
ficulty. Some  European  countries  have  passed  laws  with- 
out any  provision  for  the  securing  of  the  compensation, 
leaving  everything  to  the  individual  initiative  of  the  em- 
ployer; but  in  the  United  States  it  has  been  unusual  not  to 
compel  some  kind  of  insurance.  In  Maryland,  under  a 
heavy  pecuniary  penalty  and  the  added  disadvantage  of  the 
abrogation  of  his  three  common  law  defenses  in  any  suit 
arising  during  the  time  of  his  non-coverage,31  the  employer 
is  compelled  to  secure  the  compensation  due  from  him 
either  by  insuring  in  the  State  Accident  Fund,  in  an  old 
line  casualty  insurance  company  or  mutual  insurance  asso- 
ciation authorized  to  carry  workmen's  compensation  insur- 
ance and  under  the  supervision  of  the  insurance  commis- 
sioner, or  by  convincing  the  State  Industrial  Accident  Com- 
mission that  he  is  strong  enough  financially  to  carry  his  own 
insurance.32  The  Industrial  Accident  Commission  has  wide 
powers  of  inquisition  and  compulsion  with  reference  to  the 
methods  which  the  employer  shall  adopt ;  and  the  state  in- 
surance commissioner  has  authority  to  determine  the  ade- 
quacy and  to  regulate  the  compensation  rates  of  the  pri- 
vate companies.83 

The  State  Accident  Fund  is  a  creature  of  the  act.34  Full 
permission  is  given  to  the  commission  to  establish  this  fund 
by  the  underwriting  of  insurance  policies  under  the  act. 
The  Maryland  fund  is  in  the  nature  of  a  straight  insurance 
scheme  as  contrasted  with  the  compulsory,  state-adminis- 
tered mutual  insurance  fund  of  the  Ohio  act.  The  rules 
for  its  administration,  and  its  actual  administration,  are 
based  upon  the  experience  and  organization  of  private  in- 

81  Sees.  14  and  15. 

82  Sees.  15,  29,  and  30. 

18  Sec.  15,  as  amended  by  Laws  1916,  Ch.  597;  and  Sec.  29. 
84  See  Sees.  16-28,  as  amended  in  1916. 


66  THE   LABOR   LAW   OF   MARYLAND  [212 

surance  companies.  Full  power  to  make  rates  and  classifi- 
cations conducive  to  accident  prevention  is  granted.  Penal 
provisions  allow  the  state  fund  to  enforce  certain  regula- 
tions as  to  uniform  payrolls  or  payroll  reports  which  the 
private  companies  enforce  by  cancellation.  As  practically 
conducted,  the  fund  does  not  solicit  policies ;  and  it  has  thus 
been  able  to  quote  rates  on  the  eight  or  nine  hundred  poli- 
cies which  it  had  underwritten  at  the  end  of  1916  ten  to 
thirty  per  cent  lower  than  the  private  companies.  This 
saving  is  also  due,  in  part,  to  the  fact  that  for  the  first 
three  years  the  full  cost  of  administration  is  borne  by  the 
State ;  and,  even  after  the  first  three  years,  the  fund  is  only 
to  bear  that  part  of  the  expense  which  is  proportionate  to 
its  share  of  the  policies  written  in  the  State.35  It  is,  of 
course,  impossible  to  give  prior  to  the  lapse  of  a  period  of 
five  or  possibly  ten  years  an  opinion  of  any  value  on  the 
efficiency  or  economy  of  the  state  fund.  A  principal  ob- 
jection to  such  a  fund  is  that,  being  unable  to  refuse  any 
policy,  it  is  overburdened  with  bad  risks.  Another  objec- 
tion is  that  the  reserve  is  generally  insufficient  to  cover 
catastrophe  risk,  though  in  Maryland,  it  would  seem,  the 
entire  resources  of  the  State  are  behind  the  fund.36  Both 
of  these  as  affecting  the  possibility  of  the  passing  of  pay- 
ments are  of  utmost  importance  to  the  employee,  more  so 
perhaps  than  to  the  employer. 

The  objections  to  the  Maryland  fund,  it  is  obvious,  are 
due  to  the  fact  that  it  is  elective  and  in  competition  with 
the  private  companies.  This  fact  has  led  other  States,  nota- 
bly Ohio  and  Washington,  to  create  a  monopoly  of  insur- 
ance in  the  state  fund.  The  savings  in  administration 
would  seem  a  convincing  argument  for  this  mode  of  secur- 
ity, if  efficient  administrative  officers  could  be  procured  for 
the  state  fund  and  the  fund  in  its  entirety  could  be  kept  out 
of  politics.  This,  of  course,  is  socialistic  legislation,  and 
encounters  the  opposition  that  is  the  natural  concomitant 

85  See  Sec.  27,  as  amended  by  Laws  1916,  Ch.  597. 

86  Sec.  16,  as  amended  by  Laws  1916,  Ch.  597. 


213]          THE  WORKMEN'S  COMPENSATION  LAW  67 

of  all  socialistic  enterprises.  In  Maryland,  especially,  this 
opposition  would  be  strong  and  effective  because  of  the 
great  growth  of  Baltimore  as  a  center  of  casualty  insurance 
companies  and  the  consequent  disruption  of  business  which 
would  of  necessity  ensue. 

The  law  as  a  whole  is  administered  by  the  State  Indus- 
trial Accident  Commission,  composed  of  three  commission- 
ers appointed  by  the  governor  of  the  State  for  a  term  of 
six  years  with  an  annual  salary  of  five  thousand  dollars.37 
Provision  is  made  that  this  commission  shall  be  bi-partisan, 
but  there  is  no  attempt  to  secure  efficient  administration  at 
the  cost  of  party  politics.  The  commission  has  the  employ- 
ment of  upwards  of  fifty  clerks,  actuaries,  etc.,  with  no 
supervision  except  the  written  approval  of  the  governor  to 
the  salaries :  competitive  examinations  are  not  mentioned. 
During  the  administration  of  each  governor  the  terms  of 
at  least  two  of  the  three  commissioners  will  expire  so  that 
each  governor  will  be  able  to  change  completely  the  political 
complexion  of  a  board  which  will  annually  spend  forty 
thousand  dollars  or  over.  Whether  party  politics  is  going 
to  spoil  another  good  legislative  endeavor,  it  is,  of  course, 
impossible  to  prophesy;  but  it  seems  unpardonable  that  a 
more  efficient  check  than  public  opinion  was  not  provided 
in  the  law. 

The  principal,  and,  at  this  time,38  the  only,  office  of  the 
commission  is  in  Baltimore  City ;  but,  when  it  is  more  con- 
venient for  one  of  the  commissioners  to  go  into  another 
part  of  the  State  to  hold  a  hearing  than  it  is  for  the  claim- 
ant with  all  his  witnesses  to  travel  to  Baltimore,  advantage 
is  taken  of  the  provision  allowing  one  commissioner  to  hold 
hearings  and  make  awards  subject  to  the  approval  of  his 

87  Sees,  i  and  3.  Three  thousand  dollars  only  of  the  salary  is  paid 
by  the  State,  because  of  the  provision  of  the  Constitution  against 
appointive  officers  with  salaries  above  three  thousand  dollars  (Art. 
15,  Sec.  i).  The  other  two  thousand  dollars  is  paid  by  the  City  of 
Baltimore,  a  practice  which  has  been  recently  approved  by  the  Court 
of  Appeals  with  regard  to  the  Public  Service  Commission  in  Thrift 
v.  Laird,  125  Md.  55. 

38  1916. 


68  THE   LABOR   LAW   OF    MARYLAND  [214 

colleagues.  The  normal  course  of  proceedings,  however,  is 
for  the  entire  inquiry  to  be  conducted  at  the  home  office  by 
the  commission  as  a  whole.  When  due  notice  has  been 
given  of  an  accident  and  the  fourteen  waiting  days  have 
passed,  during  which  time  the  injured  laborer  has  been 
enjoying  medical  treatment,  the  commission  sets  a  date  five 
days  in  advance,  before  which  any  objection  to  the  pay- 
ment of  the  claim  must  be  made  and  a  hearing  requested. 
Unless  there  is  objection  the  claim  is  paid,  for  there  is 
specifically  declared  to  be  a  strong  presumption  that  "the 
claim  comes  within  the  provisions  of  the  act,  that  sufficient 
notice  was  given,  that  the  injury  was  not  occasioned  by  the 
wilful  intention  of  the  injured  employee  to  bring  about  the 
death  or  injury  of  himself  or  another,  and  that  the  injury 
did  not  result  solely  from  the  intoxication  of  the  injured 
employee  while  on  duty."39  It  is  in  these  summary  cases 
naturally  that  the  principal  economies  of  the  law  become 
apparent. 

If  the  employer  demurs  to  the  employees'  claim,  a  hear- 
ing is  set.  The  hearing  is  held  either  before  the  Accident 
Commission  or  before  a  special  arbitration  committee  ap- 
pointed by  it.40  Until  a  large  body  of  precedents  is  built 
up  it  is  not  expected  that  a  special  arbitration  committee 
will  be  often  appointed.  At  these  hearings  the  commission 
prefers  to  have  each  party  represented  by  an  attorney,  so 
that  the  case  will  be  presented  in  an  orderly  manner.  Here 
becomes  apparent  one  of  the  points  where,  in  the  practical 
operation  of  a  compensation  law,  it  departs  radically  from 
its  ideals  of  no  lawyers  and  no  hostility  between  capital  and 
labor.  The  proceedings  of  the  commission  are,  however, 
rnost  summary  in  their  nature.  There  is  no  pleading ;  com- 
mon law  rules  of  evidence  do  not  prevail.41  Only  one  of 
the  present  commissioners  is  a  lawyer,  and  the  commis- 
sioners often  question  the  witness  in  order  to  bring  out  what 

89  Sec.  62. 

40  Sec.  40. 

41  Sees.  9-10. 


215]  THE  WORKMEN'S  COMPENSATION  LAW  69 

seem  to  them  essential  points.  The  proceedings  should  be 
.equitable  rather  than  legal  in  nature  has  declared  a  Massa- 
chusetts court  in  a  recent  decision.42  In  all  investigations 
the  commission  has  "  power  to  issue  subpoenas,  compel  the 
attendance  of  witnesses,  .  .  .  compel  the  production  of 
pertinent  books,  payrolls,  accounts,  papers,  records,  docu- 
ments and  testimony,"  and  an  immunity  bath  is  provided 
against  self-incrimination  to  save  the  constitutionality  of 
the  statute.43  Every  precaution  is  taken  to  secure  swift 
and  adequate  justice  and  to  make  this  board,  though  quasi- 
judicial  in  its  procedure,  executive  in  its  action.  The  pow- 
ers of  the  commission  do  not  cease  upon  each  award,  but 
continue  like  the  powers  of  equity  courts  over  their  trustees 
and  guardians:  it  may  at  any  time  upon  due  cause  and 
notice  amend  its  awards  and  decisions.44 

"Any  employer,  employee,  beneficiary  or  person  feeling 
aggrieved  by  any  decision  of  the  commission  affecting  his 
interests  under  this  Act  may  have  the  same  reviewed  by  a 
proceeding  in  the  nature  of  an  appeal "  in  any  common  law 
court  having  jurisdiction;  "and  the  court  shall  determine 
whether  the  commission  has  justly  considered  all  the  facts 
concerning  the  injury,  whether  it  has  exceeded  the  powers 
granted  it  by  the  Act,  or  whether  it  has  misconstrued  the 
law  and  facts  applicable  in  the  case  decided."  This  appeal 
also  is  to  be  conducted  in  a  summary  manner,  but,  upon 
motion  of  either  party,  any  question  of  fact  involved  may 
be  submitted  to  a  jury.  Appeals  from  these  proceedings  lie 
to  the  Court  of  Appeals.45 

This  exposition  of  the  principles  of  the  act  demonstrates 
that  it  is  a  piece  of  legislation  passed  for  the  benefit  of  the 
laborer;  and,  insufficient  and  unsatisfactory  as  some  of  its 

42  In  re  Mut.  Liability  Ins.  Co.,  102  N.  E.  693. 
48  Sec.  7.    Contempt  of  any  of  these  orders  may  be  punished  upon 
application  to  any  judge  in  Maryland. 

44  Sec.  54.    Construed  in  Adleman  v.  Ocean  Accident,  etc.  Corp., 
130  Md.  512. 

45  Sec.  56.    See  also  Breuner  v.  Breuner,  127  Md.  189;  Frazier  v. 
Leas,  127  Md.  572. 


7O  THE   LABOR  LAW   OF   MARYLAND  [2l6 

provisions  have  been  found  to  be,  it  brings  about  a  great 
improvement  over  previous  conditions.  Besides  its  effect 
as  social  legislation,  however,  certain  legal  results  follow 
from  its  enactment. 

The  Constitutionality  of  the  Law. — From  the  legal  stand- 
point, the  most  interesting  feature  of  a  compensation  law  is 
its  constitutionality.  Frankly  considered,  the  law  requires 
that  the  money  of  one  set  of  people  shall  be  handed  over 
irrespective  of  fault  to  the  members  of  another  class  upon 
the  happening  of  a  contingency.  Such  a  law  is  a  new  de- 
parture in  American  legislation  and  presents  some  ex- 
tremely interesting  constitutional  questions.  Numerous  ar- 
guments, brilliant  and  intricate,  have  been  published  in  sup- 
port of  the  constitutionality  of  the  law,  so  that  here  there 
is  need  only  of  a  mere  outline  of  the  difficulties. 

The  fact  that  the  compensation  law  substitutes  vicarious 
liability  without  reference  to  fault  for  the  old  common  law 
liability  is  thus  met:  "Our  jurisprudence  affords  many  ex- 
amples of  legal  liability  without  fault  and  the  deprivation  of 
property  without  fault  being  attributable  to  its  owner.  The 
law  of  deodands  was  such  an  example.  .  .  .  Other  exam- 
ples are  afforded  in  the  liability  of  the  husband  for  the  torts 
.of  his  wife — the  liability  of  a  master  for  the  acts  of  his 
servants."48  Statutes  furnish  further  examples.  Munici- 
palities have  been  made  responsible  for  property  destroyed 
by  a  mob;47  railroads  have  been  made  liable  for  damage 
caused  by  sparks  from  its  engines.48  But  these  precedents 
are  not  precedents  for  the  compensation  law.  The  common 
law  instances  cited  are  merely  the  result  of  imputing  to  one 
the  fault  of  another  whose  action  he  controls,  and  the  stat- 
utes relate  to  special  objects  of  state  activity.  Compensa- 
tion laws,  on  the  other  hand,  make  an  innocent  employer 
carrying  on  a  private,  lawful  business  liable  even  for  an 
accident  occurring  in  the  course  of  that  business.  This 

48  Chicago,  R.  I.  &  R.  R.  Co.  v.  Zernicke,  183  U.  S.  582. 

47  Chicago  v.  Sturgis,  222  U.  S.  313. 

48  St.  Louis,  S.  F.  R.  Co.  v.  Mathews,  165  U.  S.  I,  and  numerous 
state  decisions. 


2i/]          THE  WORKMEN'S  COMPENSATION  LAW  71 

argument  through  precedents  does  not  lead  to  very  satis- 
factory conclusions. 

Another  argument  seeks  to  uphold  the  compensation  law 
upon  the  basis  of  the  decision  in  the  Second  Employers' 
Liability  case.49  This  decision  held  that  it  was  within  the 
power  of  Congress  so  to  change  the  rules  of  law  that  no 
railroad  could  avail  itself  of  the  three  common  law  de- 
fences of  assumption  of  risk,  contributory  negligence,  and 
fellow-servant  doctrine  in  a  damage  suit  against  it  by  an 
employee.  The  decision  merely  reiterated  the  old  opinion 
that  there  can  be  no  property  in  a  rule  of  law.60  To  try  to 
base  the  constitutionality  of  the  compensation  law  upon 
this  decision  displays  an  ignorance  of  the  distinction  between 
that  law  and  an  employers'  liability  law.  The  liability  law 
merely  abrogates  the  three  common  law  defences  and  leaves 
the  law  of  industrial  accidents  otherwise  the  same;  the 
compensation  law  provides  for  the  indiscriminate  indemni- 
fication by  an  administrative  tribunal  of  all  industrial  acci- 
dents. The  liability  law  retains  the  idea  of  fault ;  the  com- 
pensation law  imposes  a  vicarious  liability. 

A  final  case  relied  upon — and  this  time  with  more  justi- 
fication— is  the  bank  guarantee  case.61  Here  the  court  held 
constitutional  a  law  which  ordered  all  state  banks  in  the 
State  of  Oklahoma  to  contribute  to  a  guarantee  fund  from 
which  were  to  be  paid  the  losses  sustained  by  the  deposit- 
ors in  any  state  bank  by  its  insolvency.  Here  property  is 
taken  from  one  set  of  people  to  be  handed  over  to  another 
set  upon  the  happening  of  a  contingency  for  which  the  first 
set  is  often  without  fault.  In  this  respect  this  law  is  ex- 
actly similar  to  a  compensation  law,  and  this  case,  especially 
in  view  of  the  broad  language  used  by  Justice  Holmes,  is 
most  aptly  referred  to  as  a  precedent  and  an  analogue  in 
arguing  the  constitutionality  of  a  compensation  law.  But  a 
distinction  can  be  drawn.  In  the  first  place,  banking  is 

«  Mundou  v.  N.  Y.,  N.  H.  &  H.  R.  Co.,  223  U.  S.  I. 

60  Munn  v.  Illinois,  94  U.  S.  113. 

61  Noble  State  Bank  v.  Haskell,  219  U.  S.  104. 


?2  THE   LABOR   LAW   OF   MARYLAND  [2 1 8 

peculiarly  a  subject  of  state  control;  it  is  most  highly 
"affected  with  a  public  interest."  In  fact,  it  is  really  a 
public  business  entrusted  to  private  enterprise  and  almost 
any  regulation  in  furtherance  of  the  public  welfare  would 
be  justified.  In  the  second  place,  there  is  a  decided  com- 
munity of  interest  among  bankers  which  tends  to  make  them 
stand  together  and  be  somewhat  responsible  for  the  acts  of 
one  another,  so  that  the  law  merely  lends  the  sanction  of 
the  state  to  what  was  before  demanded  by  self-interest.  It 
might  be  argued  that  a  compensation  law  creates  a  com- 
munity of  interest  among  employers  in  the  promotion  of 
safety,  but  this  is  a  difficult  argument,  and  there  is  of  course 
no  special  public  interest  in  most  of  the  occupations  covered 
by  a  compensation  law.  Therefore,  though  the  bank  guar- 
antee case  is  a  weighty  precedent,  it  does  not  seem  to  be 
absolutely  conclusive. 

If  a  compulsory  compensation  law  is  to  be  frankly  up- 
held, it  will  have  to  be  upheld  as  an -exercise  of  the  police 
power.  It  was  in  the  exercise  of  this  power  that  the  Mary- 
land act  was  avowedly  passed.62  " '  Property  of  every  kind 
— it  must  be  remembered — is  held  subject  to  those  regula- 
tions which  are  necessary  for  the  common  good  and  general 
welfare.  And  the  legislature  has  the  power  to  define  the 
mode  and  manner  in  which  every  one  may  use  his  prop- 
erty.' "53  It  is  in  pursuance  of  this  power,  as  was  said  in 
the  first  chapter,  that  all  labor  legislation  is  enacted  and,  if 
we  consider  the  previous,  admittedly  constitutional  labor 
enactments,  it  will  be  easily  demonstrated  that  the  compen- 
sation law  is  merely  a  peculiar  development  of  a  well- 
established  principle. 

Since  the  Industrial  Revolution,  the  bargaining  power  of 
the  laborer  has  not  been  equal  to  that  of  the  employer. 
The  inequality  was  early  recognized  by  the  legislatures  and 

52  See  the  preamble,  Part  4. 

58  Windsor  v.  State,  103  Md.  611,  quoting  Story  on  the  Constitu- 
tion. See  also  Singer  v.  State,  72  Md.  464 ;  State  v.  Hyman,  98  Md. 
596;  64  L.  R.  A.  637;  State  v.  Gurry,  121  Md.  534;  C.  &  P.  Telephone 
Co.  v.  Board  of  Forestry,  125  Md.  666. 


219]          THE  WORKMEN'S  COMPENSATION  LAW  73 

the  courts  too  have  now  explicitly  sanctioned  the  legislative 
correction  of  this  inequality.8*  In  pursuance  of  this  policy 
of  equalization,  the  legislatures  have  never  seen  fit  to  make 
absolutely  equal  the  two  parties  to  the  labor  contract,  but 
have  instead  guaranteed  to  the  employee  certain  terms  of 
the  contract  which  were  conceived  as  necessary  to  the  "  gen- 
eral welfare  and  public  convenience/'  Thus  the  legislature 
has  passed  child  labor  laws,  hours  of  labor  laws  for  men 
and  women,  safety  and  sanitation  laws,  and  a  host  of  other 
laws  which  are  not  so  easy  of  classification.  The  compen- 
sation law  is  a  law  of  this  kind.  Conceiving  that  the  em- 
ployee could  not  successfully  bargain  with  the  employer  for 
a  sufficient  insurance  to  himself  against  industrial  accidents, 
the  legislature  by  its  fiat  introduced  such  an  insurance  term 
into  every  labor  contract.  That  is  to  say,  the  law  recognized 
that,  as  economists  had  long  contended,  the  employee  did 
not  visualize  all  the  risks  of  his  employment,  as  the  com- 
mon law  assumed  he  did,  and  demand  a  higher  wage  in  con- 
sequence thereof.  Therefore,  says  the  law,  an  implied  term 
of  every  contract  shall  be  an  adequate  compensation  in  case 
of  industrial  accident. 

That  this  term  of  the  contract  is  as  necessary  to  the  gen- 
eral welfare  as  are  the  terms  introduced  by  previous  laws 
seems  hardly  to  require  detailed  proof.  Industrial  acci- 
dents are  undoubtedly  the  principal  causes  of  poverty  and 
degradation.  If  the  prevention  of  poverty  is  not  necessary 
to  the  general  welfare  of  a  community,  what  is  ?  It  is  true 
that  the  courts,  not  however  without  criticism,  have  re- 
fused to  sanction  taxation  for  the  prevention  of  poverty. 
But,  granting  the  correctness  of  these  decisions,  they  do  not 
weaken  our  argument.  By  a  compensation  law  the  State 
does  not  tax  for  the  prevention  of  destitution;  it  merely 
decrees  that  industry  shall  riot  prosper  from  the  mishaps 
of  the  employee,  just  as  it  formerly  declared  that  industry 
should  not  prosper  from  the  labor  of  children.  Industry 
must  be  conducted  legitimately  and  it  is  certainly  within 

««  Holden  v.  Hardy,  169  U.  S.  366. 


74  THE  LABOR   LAW   OP   MARYLAND  [22O 

the  power  of  the  State  to  decree  that  industry  shall  bear 
the  cost  of  all  its  materials,  the  cost  of  the  life  and  limbs  of 
its  laborers,  as  well  as  of  the  inanimate  equipment  and  raw 
stuffs. 

In  thus  briefly  outlining  the  constitutional  difficulties 
which  accompany  a  compensation  law,  it  is  of  course  im- 
possible to  consider  the  finer  points  of  law.  Equally  im- 
possible is  it  to  examine  some  minor  constitutional  ques- 
tions which  may  be  raised  with  regard  to  the  Maryland 
law,  but  which  are  not  essential  to  the  compensation  prin- 
ciple. 

From  the  practical  legal  standpoint,  the  most  important 
result  of  the  compensation  law  will  be  to  render  obsolete 
in  the  occupations  covered  all  the  intricate  tort  law  dealing 
with  the  relation  between  employer  and  employee.65  As 
has  been  so  often  iterated,  the  employer  can  no  longer  plead 
contributory  negligence,  the  doctrine  of  assumption  of  risk, 
and  the  fellow  servant  doctrine  in  defense  of  a  claim 
against  him  by  an  employee.  The  law  of  contributory 
negligence  will  continue  to  exist  in  other  damage  suits,  but 
with  this  exception  these  doctrines  will  ultimately  pass  out 
of  existence.  With  them  will  pass  a  mass  of  complicated 
and  unsettled  law.  No  longer  will  there  be  a  question  of 
what  risks  the  employee  assumes  on  entering  an  employ- 
ment, of  what  kinds  of  instruments  the  employer  must  fur- 
nish, whether  a  defect  in  a  machine  is  latent  or  patent,  or 
whether  the  employer  has  engaged  efficient  fellow  servants 
to  work  with  the  employee.  No  longer,  in  short,  will  it  be 
necessary  to  enumerate  the  duties  of  the  employer  to  the 
employee,  for  they  will  all  become  merged  in  one  duty, — 
to  compensate  him  for  an  industrial  accident.  No  longer 
again  will  it  be  necessary  to  determine  who  are  fellow  ser- 
vants, for  the  doctrine  relating  to  them  is  also  abolished. 
By  an  amendment  of  1916  one  of  the  elaborations  of  this 
rule  is  explicitly  abrogated.  If  an  employee  of  a  subcon- 
tractor is  injured  he  may  collect  his  compensation  directly 

56  See  Harlan,  Domestic  Relations,  Part  V. 


22 1]          THE  WORKMEN'S  COMPENSATION  LAW  75 

from  the  contractor  in  chief,  who  will  then  contest  with 
the  subcontractor  the  ultimate  liability.86  Thus,  so  far  as 
the  workingman  is  concerned,  the  doctrine  of  independent 
contractor  and  with  it  the  doctrine  of  vice-principal  is 
abolished. 

In  place  of  this  branch  of  the  law  there  is  growing  up  a 
new  series  of  cases  deciding  what  is  an  accidental  injury 
"  arising  out  of  "  and  "  in  the  course  of  employment."  This 
line  of  cases,  if  we  can  judge  from  present  indications, 
threatens  to  become  as  long  as  those  which  have  been  over- 
thrown by  the  act ;  but  they  will  hardly  result  in  such  diffi- 
cult law.  I  have  already  quoted  the  definition  adopted  by 
the  Maryland  Accident  Commission. 

Finally  a  change  must  be  noted  in  the  relation  of  the  em- 
ployee to  the  insurance  carrier.  Under  the  common  law  the 
insurance  carrier  bears  no  special  relation  .to  the  employee ; 
it  was  merely  the  indemnifier  of  the  employer.  Under  the 
compensation  law  "  the  insurance  carrier  occupies  the  posi- 
tion of  surety  for  the  employer,  to  secure  the  fulfillment  of 
any  liability  which  may  be  determined  to  have  arisen."57 
The  liability  of  the  carrier  to  the  employee  is  a  primary  lia- 
bility jointly  with  the  employer,  and  it  is  not  excused  from 
payment  of  the  compensation  by  the  bankruptcy  or  insol- 
vency of  the  employer.68  Nor,  of  course,  on  the  other  hand 
is  the  employer  relieved  by  insuring  in  a  bankrupt  or  in- 
solvent insurance  carrier. 

56  Laws  1916,  Ch.  597,  adding  Sec.  6oA  to  the  Code. 

67  Brenner  v.  Brenner,  127  Md.  189. 

68  Code  1914,  Art.  101,  Sec.  36. 


CHAPTER  IV 
THE  CONDITIONS  OF  EMPLOYMENT 

The  enactments  of  the  state  regulating  the  conditions  of 
employment  of  the  workingman,  the  safety  and  sanitation 
laws,  are  the  most  important  features  of  a  constructive 
labor  legislation  program.  True,  the  activity  of  the  state 
in  the  fields  discussed  in  the  two  preceding  chapters  is  most 
essential  to  the  welfare  of  the  laborer,  but  the  statutes  re- 
lating to  the  labor  union  and  the  compensation  law  are  for 
the  most  part  amendatory  of  the  common  law.  Such  inter- 
ference of  the  state  in  labor  matters  was  directed  to  making 
more  efficient  the  existing  means  for  the  reform  of  labor 
conditions,  that  is,  to  the  development  of  the  union  and  to 
the  modernizing  of  the  common  law  to  fit  present  day  in- 
dustrial conditions ;  the  remainder  of  this  study  will  be  con- 
cerned with  the  extent  to  which  the  state  should  intervene 
in  private  affairs  in  the  attempt  to  ameliorate  labor  condi- 
tions. 

The  most  important  matter  with  regard  to  which  the 
state  exercises  its  power  of  intervention  is  the  regulation  of 
the  environment  in  which  the  laborer  conducts  his  daily 
task.  This  dogmatic  statement  might  be  strenuously  con- 
tested by  some  labor  reform  advocates  and  by  some  econ- 
omists, but  their  position  seems  to  be  much  weakened  by 
an  unproportioned  estimate  of  present  conditions  and  future 
possibilities.  The  contention  that  the  foremost  problems 
and  concerns  of  labor  are  unemployment,  wages  and  hours 
may  be  admitted  without  disproving  the  contention  that  the 
prime  object  of  state  activity  is  the  safeguarding  of  the 
employee  in  his  daily  work.  Not  only  historically  was  this 
the  first  concern  of  the  state  in  industrial  conditions,  but 
practically  it  affects  more  intimately  and  more  uniformly 

76 


223]  THE   CONDITIONS   OF    EMPLOYMENT  77 

the  whole  mass  of  workingmen.  State  employment  officers 
may  find  work  for  a  part  of  the  unemployed  who  rarely 
comprise  more  than  eight  per  cent  of  the  working  class ;  the 
state  may  set  a  minimum  wage  for  the  hopelessly  weak  bar- 
gainers ;  and  the  state  may  regulate  hours  in  the  extremely 
overworked  trades ;  but,  in  all  these,  the  great  majority  of 
the  workers  are  working  out  their  own  salvation  with  con- 
stantly increasing  success.  Safety  and  sanitary  legislation, 
on  the  other  hand,  affects  every  laborer.  The  unit  of  re- 
form, so  to  speak,  is  the  factory,  not  the  individual ;  and  it 
is  this  distinction  which  brings  these  factory  laws  peculiarly 
within  the  function  of  the  state  and  takes  them  out  of  the 
scope  of  private  and  voluntary  means  of  reform. 

It  is  hardly  necessary  at  this  late  date  to  argue  that  safety 
and  sanitation  legislation  is  proper  in  the  present  status  of 
industrial  conditions.  Npt  even  the  most  extreme  adherent 
of  laissez-faire  can  deny  that  competition  and  the  absence 
of  regulation  reduce  the  conditions  of  labor  below  the 
standards  of  decency  and  good  health.  Even  the  most  ex- 
treme individualists  admit  that  the  police  power  of  the  state 
extends  to  the  reasonable  regulation  of  working  conditions. 
Only  the  opposition  of  the  capitalist,  who  naturally  objects 
to  the  expenditure  of  his  money  for  the  benefit  of  others, 
and  that  without  any  easily  perceptible  advantage  to  him- 
self, deters  the  legislators  from  enacting  the  fine,  ideal  laws 
which  have  been  drafted  for  them. 

Regulation  by  Commission. — There  is,  however,  some 
dispute  with  reference  to  the  preferable  mode  of  regulation 
if  not  to  the  necessity  and  kind  of  regulation.  Until  five 
years  ago  all  safety  and  sanitary  laws,  if  complete,  were 
lengthy,  minute  enactments  covering  every  known  condition 
of  employment  and  laying  down  absolute  laws  to  apply  to 
every  preconceived  condition.  Set  screws,  unguarded  belts, 
and  other  dangerous  devices  were  absolutely  outlawed,  but 
there  the  law  stopped.  In  1911  Wisconsin,1  drawing  a  les- 

1  Wisconsin  Laws,  Sees.  2394-41  to  2394-71. 


78  THE   LABOR   LAW   OF   MARYLAND  [224 

son  from  the  evolution  of  the  governmental  control  of  rates, 
applied  the  commission  idea  of  regulation  to  industrial  con- 
ditions. A  general  law  providing  for  safety  in  industrial 
occupations  was  enacted  and  a  commission  with  ordinance 
powers  was  appointed  to  issue  orders  in  compliance  with 
this  general  law.  Full  discretionary  powers  are  substituted 
for  absolute  and  arbitrary  regulation.  Finding  it  impossi- 
ble to  foresee  every  possible  contingency  in  which  the  labor 
law  would  be  applied  and  conceiving  it  equally  impossible 
to  leave  anything  to  the  easily  corrupted  discretion  of  the 
inspectors,  the  legislature  created  a  competent  and  respon- 
sible board  to  carry  out  its  wishes.  The  idea  of  this  fourth 
branch  of  government,  the  administrative  branch,  as  it  is 
sometimes  called,2  is  not  new  in  American  politics.  The 
federal  government  has  found  it  advisable  in  handling  in- 
terstate commercial  and  industrial  conditions  and  the  State 
governments  have  rather  generally  adopted  the  same  means 
of  controlling  their  public  service  corporations  and  of  ad- 
ministering their  workmen's  compensation  laws.  In  the 
field  of  labor  legislation  the  experiment  of  Wisconsin  has 
not  failed  to  stimulate  imitation;  both  Massachusetts  and 
New  York  among  the  Eastern  States  having  to  a  consider- 
able degree  adopted  this  means  of  regulation.  . 

From  the  legal  standpoint  the  commission  is  an  investi- 
gating agency  with,  it  is  true,  considerably  more  power  to 
secure  practical  benefits  from  its  investigations  than  have 
most  investigating  committees.  The  significance  of  this 
aspect  of  the  commission's  work  is  most  obvious.  As  has 
been  said,  the  regulation  of  the  environment  of  employ- 
ment is  easily  within  the  police  power  of  the  state — the 
protection  of  health  and  safety  is  the  most  elemental  exer- 
cise of  this  power.  The  only  limitation  upon  this  control  is 
that  it  must  be  reasonable  both  in  the  manner  of  its  appli- 

2  Most  of  this  discussion  of  the  industrial  commission  scheme  of 
government  has  been  suggested  by  an  article  by  J.  R.  Commons, 
published  by  the  Wisconsin  Industrial  Commission,  most  of  which 
appeared  in  The  Survey  for  January  4,  1913. 


225]  THE   CONDITIONS   OF  EMPLOYMENT  79 

cation  and  in  the  discrimination  necessarily  involved  in  its 
exercise.  Because  of  the  manner  in  which  the  commission 
formulates  its  rules,  its  ordinances  have  the  prima  facie 
weight  of  reasonableness  greater  than  in  the  case  of  legis- 
lative enactments. 

The  commission  is  assisted  in  drawing  up  its  orders  by 
unpaid,  advisory  subcommittees  on  the  various  subjects  of 
safety  and  sanitation.  These  subcommittees  are  not  com- 
posed of  experts  fixing  ideal  regulations,  which,  as  Mr. 
Commons  says,  may  be  reasonable  in  a  superregulated  coun- 
try like  Germany,  but  hardly  in  the  United  States ;  they  are 
where  possible  drawn  mainly  from  the  ranks  of  the  em- 
ployers and  employees,  with  occasionally  one  or  two  ex- 
perts who  are  usually  taken  from  state  boards  or  insurance 
companies.  These  subcommittees  deliberate,  hear  witnesses 
in  the  same  manner  as  legislative  committees,  and  draw  up 
rules  which  are  referred  to  the  commission  as  "general 
orders."  These  orders  are  published  and  then  considered  at 
hearings  held  before  the  commission.  If  amendments  are 
suggested  to  the  commission  at  these  hearings  and  approved 
by  them  the  report  of  the  advisors  is  recommitted  to  them. 
When  finally  approved  by  the  commission,  the  "general 
orders  "  are  enacted  to  go  into  effect  thirty  days  after  final 
publication.  The  orders  can,  of  .course,  be  attacked  in 
court ;  but,  as  the  commission  has  sat  at  its  hearings  in  its 
judicial  capacity  its  findings  are  presumed  to  be  reasonable 
and  constitutional,  and  even  if  before  the  court  new  evi- 
dence is  unearthed  to  prove  the  unreasonableness  of  the 
order  the  order  is  referred  back  to  the  commission  for  a 
rehearing;  the  court  does  not  absolutely  annul  the  order. 
Moreover,  since  these  orders  are  adopted  by  a  body  com- 
posed largely  of  employers,  little  ground  is  afforded  for  the 
objection  of  arbitrariness  and  public  opinion  has  a  strong 
lever  against  the  recalcitrant  capitalist. 

Moreover,  through  its  power  to  enforce  the  factory  law, 
to  control  inspection  and  to  enact  "special  orders"  to  fit 
unforeseen  contingencies,  the  commission  is  enabled  to  ad- 


8O  THE   LABOR   LAW    OF    MARYLAND  [226 

minister  the  law  more  efficiently  and  some  would  be  tempted 
to  say  more  humanely  than  it  otherwise  could.  As  the  com- 
mission itself  characterizes  this  part  of  its  work,  "  the  work 
of  the  inspectors  of  the  commission  is  not  to  ferret  out 
points  of  danger  and  to  tabulate  them,  but  it  is  chiefly  to  do 
constructive  educational  work.  .  .  .  The  one  point  which 
the  commissioners  most  strongly  emphasize  with  the  depu- 
ties is  that  they  must  so  present  safety  work  that  the  em- 
ployers will  become  interested  and  will  appreciate  its  prac- 
tical value  from  the  standpoint  of  efficiency."3  The  field 
agents  of  the  commission  are  "deputies,"  not  "inspectors." 
They  confer  with  each  employer  and  if  there  is  an  excep- 
tional situation  in  his  plant,  a  "special  order"  is  obtained 
from  the  commission  to  prevent  any  irritation  from  the 
operation  of  the  general  orders.  The  same  principles  un- 
derlie the  educational  work  of  the  commission  among  the 
employees,  for  it  is  well  recognized  that  safety  results  quite 
as  much  from  the  improved  esprit  de  corps  of  the  workers 
as  from  mechanical  safety  devices. 

In  short,  everything  reasonable  is  done  to  decrease  the 
enormous  loss  of  life  and  limb  which  had  come  to  be  con- 
sidered a  natural  concomitant  of  modern  industry.  "Rea- 
sonableness "  may  be  said  to  be  the  watchword  of  the  com- 
mission. The  effect  of  its  policy  has  been  to  reduce  irrita- 
tion and  to  keep  the  factory  law  out  of  the  courts.  It  seems 
beyond  doubt  that  this  plan  of  legislation  will  be  held  con- 
stitutional, for  the  courts  have  recognized  this  fourth  branch 
of  government  in  other  fields ;  and  once  the  legality  of  the 
fundamental  law  is  established  there  can  hardly  be  further 
dispute  with  reference  to  an  order  enacted  as  these  orders 
are.  Moreover,  the  new  status  of  the  inspection  depart- 
ment will  keep  most  cases  out  of  court,  for  it  is  human 
nature  to  respond  more  readily  to  solicitous  appeals  than 
to  threatening  commands.  In  fact,  it  has  been  found  in 
Wisconsin  that  once  an  intelligent  employer  has  been  shown 

8  Report  of  the  Wisconsin  Industrial  Commission  on  Allied  Func- 
tions for  the  Two  Years  Ending  June  30,  1914,  p.  9. 


22/J  THE   CONDITIONS  OF   EMPLOYMENT  8 1 

the  most  evident  deficiencies  of  his  establishment,  his  own 
sense  of  justice  will  often  prompt  him  to  undertake  a  thor- 
ough rehabilitation  of  his  plant. 

In  Maryland,  however,  this  scheme  has  not  obtained  any 
considerable  foothold,  and,  though  it  is  instructive  to  ex- 
amine it  in  a  purely  disinterested  spirit  as  a  more  efficient 
system  to  which  we  are  inevitably  tending,  yet  such  a  study 
does  not  take  us  far  in  the  investigation  of  the  existing  laws. 
Maryland,  however,  is  woefully  deficient  in  its  factory  leg- 
islation ;  and,  even  in  studying  the  existing  laws,  this  chap- 
ter will  be  as  often  a  consideration  of  ideals  as  of  actual 
facts. 

Fire  Protection. — The  fire  hazard  can  without  doubt  be 
said  to  be  the  most  important  safety  problem  demanding 
solution  by  the  State  at  the  present  day.  Yet  practically 
every  State,  unless  it  has  adopted  a  new  building  code, 
within  the  last  few  years  has  taken  decidedly  inadequate 
measures  to  meet  the  danger.  Maryland  is  no  exception. 
Despite  the  general  agreement  that  "an  ounce  of  preven- 
tion is  worth  a  pound  of  cure,"  the  legislature  of  Maryland 
allows  every  city  and  county  within  its  bounds  to  expend 
thousands  in  maintaining  an  elaborate  fire  department  and, 
with  the  exception  of  the  City  of  Baltimore,  provides  no 
fire  prevention  law.  Even  in  Baltimore  the  laws  and  ordi- 
nances aimed  at  the  prevention  of  fire  are  not  at  all  in 
proportion  to  the  hazard.  It  needs  a  tragedy  to  arouse  the 
American  public  to  action  and,  because  as  yet  there  has  been 
no  holocaust  in  Baltimore,  we  are  content  to  await  one  be- 
fore enacting  the  proper  laws. 

Practically  the  entire  fire  law  of  Baltimore  and,  in  con- 
sidering this  subject,  Baltimore  will  take  the  place  of  Mary- 
land as  the  unit  of  discussion  since  the  fire  hazard  has  been 
considered  important  enough  for  legislation  only  in  this 
city — practically  the  entire  fire  law  of  Baltimore  is  in  the 
hands  of  the  building  inspector.  Now,  at  the  beginning  of 
this  chapter,  the  excellencies  of  an  elastic  law  were  ex- 
tolled; but  the  fire  law  is  one  wherein  certain  fundamental 
6 


82  THE   LABOR   LAW   OF    MARYLAND  [228 

maxims  and  orders  can  be  laid  down  with  precision,  and 
have  been  laid  down  in  states  where  legislation  has  been 
carefully  enacted,  as  in  New  York.  Moreover,  when  the 
law  is  elastic  it  should  be  administered  by  a  competent  com- 
mission under  some  pressure  to  enact  orders  and  not  by  the 
arbitrary  will  of  one  political  appointee  to  office.  Of  the 
fire  laws  affecting  places  of  labor  which  do  not  depend 
upon  the  discretion  of  the  inspector,  one  forbids  the  "pro- 
prietor of  any  sweatshop  or  factory  where  four  or  more 
persons  are  employed  to  use  any  coal  oil,  gasoline,  etc.  .  .  . 
for  the  purpose  of  lighting  or  heating  in  any  form."4  Not 
only  is  this  the  only  absolute  provision  of  the  fire  law,  but, 
as  far  as  I  can  discover,  it  is  the  only  provision  looking  to 
fire  prevention  and  not  to  fire  escape.  Another  law  does  in 
a  way  provide  a  barrier  against  fire  in  decreeing  the  fire- 
proof construction  of  the  first  floor  of  buildings  to  be  built 
after  1906  ;5  but  this  fire  prevention  is  in  the  nature  of  a 
protection  to  the  physical  structure  of  the  workshop  and  not 
to  the  lives  of  the  workers,  for  experience  has  demonstrated 
that,  as  far  as  human  life  is  concerned,  fireproof  buildings 
are  as  dangerous  to  those  in  the  buildings  as  non-fireproof 
structures. 

These  two  laws  also  provide  for  a  means  of  escape ;  and 
in  this  respect  are  of  value,  but  being  incomplete  these  pro- 
visions are  less  important  than  those  which  have  just  been 
considered.  In  the  latter  law  it  is  ordered  that,  in  all  new 
buildings,  "the  entire  stairway  shall  be  built  of  fireproof 
material,"  but  as  the  best  fire  escape  is  often  useless  if  it 
is  open  to  the  inroads  of  smoke  and  flame,  the  omission  to 
provide  for  a  fireproof  enclosure  around  the  escape  robs 
this  portion  of  the  law  of  most  of  its  value.  The  earlier 
law  commands  fire  escapes  in  sweatshops  or  factories 
"where  four  or  more  persons  are  employed  as  garment 
workers  on  other  than  the  first  floor  "  of  the  building.  The 
qualification  of  garment  worker  is,  of  course,  pernicious ; 

«  Laws  1898,  Ch.  123 ;  Baltimore  City  Code  1906,  Art.  4,  Sec.  280. 
5  Baltimore  City  Code  1906,  Art.  3,  Sec.  82. 


229]  THE   CONDITIONS   OF   EMPLOYMENT  83 

and  it  is  alleged  that  this  provision  of  the  building  code  is 
further  weakened  by  the  arbitrary  interpretation  of  the 
word  fire  escape  by  the  building  inspector  whose  require- 
ments are  met  by  one  unenclosed  fireproof  staircase  or  even 
by  two  wooden  staircases  in  separate  parts  of  the  building.8 

The  other  laws  enforced  by  the  building  inspector  are 
even  more  lax  and  inefficient,  and  they  are  to  a  certain  de- 
gree overlapping  and  confusing.  One  provides  that  "all 
manufactories  employing  twenty-five  or  more  persons  .  .  , 
[shall]  have  the  proper  means  of  exit  in  case  of  fire  or 
panic  "  in  the  discretion  of  the  inspector  of  buildings.7  An 
ordinance  of  the  mayor  and  City  Council  of  Baltimore 
makes  the  same  stipulation  for  buildings  in  which  five  or 
more  are  employed  ;8  and  a  final  provision  decrees  that  any 
building  "in  which  operatives  are  employed  in  any  of  the 
stories  above  the  first  story  shall  be  provided  with  such  fire 
escapes,  alarms  and  doors  as  shall  be  directed  and  approved 
by  the  inspector  of  buildings."9  This  official  has  issued  few 
orders  of  any  importance. 

The  whole  situation  is  unsatisfactory.  The  fire  code  is 
incomplete  and  far  below  the  requirements  of  a  modern 
industrial  city.  It  is  true  that  there  has  been  no  astounding 
loss  of  life  in  any  fire  in  Baltimore,  but  this  must  be  due 
more  to  individual  endeavor  than  to  State  supervision ;  and, 
moreover,  the  per  capita  monetary  loss  in  Baltimore  is  still 
oppressively  high  as  compared  with  European  cities  and  the 
foremost  American  cities.  A  systematic  revision  of  the  fire 
law  should  be  undertaken.  In  this  respect  Baltimore  might 
profit  by  the  experience  of  New  York.  After  the  terrible 
Triangle  Waist  fire,  New  York  with  the  aid  of  the  Factory 
Investigating  Commission  devised  and  to  a  great  degree 
enacted  a  complete  system  of  fire  laws.10  This  system, 

6  Miss  Anna  Herkner,  then  Assistant  Chief  of  Maryland  Bureau 
of  Statistics,  is  the  authority  for  this  statement.     See  also  report  of 
this  Bureau  for  1912,  p.  75. 

7  Baltimore  City  Code  1906,  Art.  3,  Sec.  80. 

8  Ordinances  1008-1909,  No.  155,  Sec.  3,  Par.  6. 
8  Baltimore  City  Code  1006,  Art.  3,  Sec.  83. 

10  See  New  York  Senate  Documents  1913,  vol.  13,  no.  36,  pt.  I,  pp. 
53-89;  and  New  York  Consolidated  Laws,  Ch.  31,  Sees.  79-83. 


84  THE   LABOR  LAW  OF   MARYLAND  [23° 

though  in  its  details  entirely  too  stringent  for  the  necessi- 
ties of  Baltimore,  might  well  be  adopted  in  its  fundamentals 
in  this  city.  As  a  prevention  against  fire,  cleanliness  and 
carefulness  are  the  two  essentials.  Fireproof  receptacles 
should,  therefore,  be  required  for  all  inflammable  waste  and 
rubbish,  and  these  receptacles  should  be  emptied  at  least 
once  a  day.  Gas  jets  in  factories  should  be  enclosed  by 
globes  or  otherwise  protected  and  all  smoking  in  factories 
should  be  prohibited  under  penalty.  Furthermore,  to  check 
incipient  fires  automatic  sprinklers  should  be  installed. 
These,  the  New  York  commission  says,  are  absolutely  nec- 
essary above  the  seventh  floor  on  account  of  the  limitations 
of  the  fire  fighting  apparatus,  but  these  limitations  do  not 
trouble  us  much  in  Baltimore  for  the  simple  reason  that 
,  few  of  our  factories  are  over  six  stories  in  height.  For  the 
benefit  of  the  factory  owner,  it  may  be  said  that  these 
sprinklers  have  proved  their  worth  in  from  seventy-five 
to  ninety-five  per  cent  of  the  cases  in  which  they  have  been 
tested  by  actual  conditions,  and  that,  moreover,  they  pay 
for  themselves  in  reduced  insurance  rates. 

For  the  protection  of  those  caught  within  the  building 
by  a  fire  the  commission  formulated  minute  and  elaborate 
rules.  A  fire  alarm  system,  for  which  in  Maryland  there  is 
an  inadequate  provision,  and  regularly  conducted  fire  drills 
participated  in  by  all  the  occupants  of  the  building  are  con- 
ceived as  a  prime  essential  to  avert  panics.  Unhampered 
and  quick  access  to  the  exits  on  the  various  floors  is  also 
a  desideratum  which  is  so  often  sacrificed  to  the  demands 
for  space.  For  the  fire  escapes  themselves  elaborate  rules 
are  laid  down.  In  the  first  place,  outside  escapes  are  uni- 
formly discouraged.  These  escapes  are  practically  of  little 
use,  for  the  inmates  are  not  accustomed  to  use  them;  and 
if  in  a  panic  a  few  find  them  these  few  are  often  too  be- 
wildered to  use  them  efficiently.  Moreover,  in  winter  the 
outside  escapes  are  often  slippery,  and  the  smoke  and  flames 
pouring  out  of  a  window  opening  on  them  render  them  en- 
tirely useless.  The  most  efficient  escapes  are  horizontal 


231]  THE   CONDITIONS  OF  EMPLOYMENT  8$ 

exits  through  a  fire  wall  traversing  the  whole  length  of  the 
building  from  ground  to  roof.  This  divides  the  structure 
into  two  fireproof  compartments  and,  it  is  perfectly  obvi- 
ous, furnishes  an  ideal  means  of  escape.  If  this  is  imprac- 
ticable the  same  end  may  be  attained  by  the  cooperative  use 
by  two  buildings  of  the  party  wall.  An  enclosed  fireproof 
staircase  within  or  attached  to  the  building  is  another  ap- 
proved method  of  escape  and  if  large  enough,  this  staircase 
is  perfectly  efficient.  The  New  York  building  code  fur- 
nishes minute  regulations  as  to  the  relation  of  the  number 
of  occupants  to  the  width  of  the  various  kinds  of  fire  es- 
capes, but  what  has  been  said  is  sufficient  to  show  the  mag- 
nitude of  the  improvement  possible  and  necessary  in 
Maryland. 

Protective  Devices. — In  its  provisions  for  the  safeguard- 
ing of  dangerous  machines  the  Maryland  labor  law  is,  if 
anything,  more  deficient  than  its  provisions  against  fire. 
There  are  a  few  laws  decreeing  the  inspection  of  scaffold- 
ing11 and  boilers12  with  provisions  for  their  safety,  but  that 
is  about  all.  There  are,  it  is  true,  some  general  provisions 
on  the  statute  books,  but  these,  though  they  might  be  most 
prolific  and  efficient,  are  for  the  most  part  entirely  abortive. 
Thus  in  the  compensation  law13  reference  is  made  to  the 
power  of  the  Accident  Commission  to  order  safety  devices 
in  the  factories ;  but  as  yet  this  power  has  not  been  exer- 
cised, and  even  if  it  were,  the  exercise  would  possibly  be 
unconstitutional  because  of  the  lack  of  notice  in  the  title  of 
the  act.  Again,  the  building  inspector  has  the  power  to  com- 
pel the  repair  or  reconstruction  of  parts  of  buildings  which 
"  endanger  the  safety  of  their  occupants,"14  and  under  his 
power  to  issue  permits  for  electrical  machines15  he  may 
compel  the  use  of  safety  devices ;  but  these  provisions  have 
been  bootless.  These  deficiencies  in  Maryland  are  especially 

11  Code  1911,  Art.  48,  Sees.  75-79. 

12  Baltimore  City  Charter  1915,  Sees.  572-589. 

18  Laws  1914,  Ch.  800,  Sec.  54.    Code  1914,  Art.  101,  Sec.  55. 
14  Baltimore  City  Ordinances  1908-1909,  No.  155,  Sec.  3,  Par.  7. 
18  Baltimore  City  Code  1906,  Ords.  Art.  3,  Sec.  45. 


86  THE  LABOR   LAW   OF   MARYLAND  [232 

glaring  when  it  is  remembered  that  Wisconsin  and  Massa- 
chusetts by  means  of  orders  from  their  industrial  commis- 
sions and  New  York  by  means  of  legislative  enactments 
and  orders  have  formulated  an  elaborate  system  of  safety 
regulations  for  the  benefit  of  their  working  people. 

Under  the  head  of  safety  devices,  though  here  the  per- 
sonal rather  than  the  material  element  is  concerned,  may 
be  mentioned  the  full-crew  railroad  law.18  This,  however, 
the  railroads  have  demonstrated  to  be  not  a  valid  safety 
measure,  but  a  mere  sop  to  the  unions. 

Requiring  the  same  brief  mention,  but  actually  of  much 
more  importance,  are  the  safety  and  inspection  provisions 
for  mines  in  Alleghany  and  Garrett  counties.17  These  are 
minute  and  technical  provisions,  an  extended  discussion  of 
which  would  hardly  lend  interest  to  this  study.  The  details 
are  most  technical  and  quite  beyond  the  comprehension  of 
a  layman.  Suffice  it  to  say  that  the  coal  mines  of  Maryland 
are  considered  as  safe  as  any  in  the  country,  but  whether 
that  is  because  of  these  enactments  or  because  of  the  in- 
herent nature  of  the  mines  would  require  an  investigation 
quite  beyond  the  scope  of  this  monograph. 

Sanitation. — In  the  field  of  sanitary  legislation  the  statute 
book  of  Maryland  until  the  legislative  session  of  1914  was 
equally  deficient.  In  that  year  special  laws  regulating  tene- 
ment houses  and  food-producing  establishments  set  rather 
high  standards  in  those  particular  fields,  but  left  the  gen- 
eral law  totally  inadequate.  There  was  prior  to  1914  a 
general  law  providing  that  "all  factories,  etc.  ...  in  this 
State  shall  be  kept  in  a  cleanly  condition  and  free  from 
effluvia  arising  from  any  drain,  privy  or  other  nuisance ;  and 
no  factory,  manufacturing  establishment  or  workshop  shall 
be  so  overcrowded  while  work  is  carried  on  therein  as  to 
be  injurious  to  the  health  of  the  persons  employed  therein, 
and  every  such  factory,  etc.,  shall  be  well  and  sufficiently 

j£_ 

16  Code  191 1,  Art.  23,  Sees.  331-335. 

17  Code  Public  Local  Laws  1888,  Art.  i,  Sees.  207-209;  Art.  12, 
Sec.  161-164. 


23 3J  THE    CONDITIONS   OF   EMPLOYMENT  8/ 

lighted  and  ventilated  in  such  manner  as  to  render  harm- 
less, as  far  as  practical,  all  gases,  etc.,  generated  in  the 
course  of  the  process  .  .  .  carried  on  therein,  which  may 
be  injurious  to  health";18  but  the  Bureau  of  Industrial  Sta- 
tistics and  Inspection  to  which  by  means  of  a  court  pro- 
ceeding was  entrusted  the  enforcement  of  this  law  found  it 
absolutely  impracticable  because  of  the  generality  of  its  pro- 
visions. It  was  impossible  to  convict  in  any  court  of  justice: 
an  essential  of  a  criminal  statute  is  definiteness.  The  legis- 
lature in  1914  repealed  this  law,  and  substituted  therefor 
a  law  requiring  the  licensing  of  all  places  manufacturing 
"articles  of  clothing,  hats,  gloves,  furs,  feathers,  artificial 
flowers,  purses,  cigars  or  cigarettes."19  The  only  condition 
precedent  to  the  grant  of  this  license  is  the  necessity  of  a 
minimum  of  five  hundred  cubic  feet  of  air  space  for  every 
person  employed — a  necessary  provision,  but  not  of  highly 
practical  value — and  the  compliance  with  the  existing  laws 
and  ordinances  applying  to  these  workshops.  The  real  pur- 
pose of  this  law  as  acknowledged  by  its  sponsors,  the  indus- 
trial bureau,  was  not  to  effect  an  improvement  of  labor 
conditions,  but  to  show  matters  in  their  true  light,  to  ex- 
pose the  real  status  of  factory  regulation,  to  relieve  the 
Board  of  Labor  of  the  responsibility  of  enforcing  a  practi- 
cally nonexistent  law  and  to  shift  this  responsibility  to  the 
city  officials  who  have  the  real  means  of  coercion. 

This  law,  it  is  obvious,  is  merely  an  additional  means  of 
enforcing  the  general  laws  of  the  State  in  these  specified 
industries.  There  is,  however,  no  general  enactment  in 
Maryland  applying  throughout  the  State;  the  nearest  ap- 
proach to  a  general  sanitary  provision  is  an  ordinance  of 
Baltimore  City  decreeing  separate  toilets  for  the  sexes  to 
be  kept  "  in  a  cleanly  and  safe  condition."20  Therefore,  if 
an  industry  is  not  located  in  a  dwelling  or  tenement  house, 
if  it  is  not  engaged  in  manufacturing  food  products,  and 

18  Laws  1884,  Ch.  265.    Code  1904,  Art.  27,  Sec.  243. 

19  Laws  1914,  Ch.  779,  Sec.  246. 


»  Laws  i8«4,  Ch.  205.    Lode  1904,  Art.  27,  be 

19  Laws  1914,  Ch.  779,  Sec.  246. 

20  Baltimore  City  Code  1906,  Art.  14,  Sec.  158. 


88  THE   LABOR   LAW   OF   MARYLAND  [234 

if  it  is  not  in  Baltimore  City,  it  has  to  comply  with  abso- 
lutely no  sanitary  regulations,  and,  indeed,  in  these  non- 
regulated  industries  the  sanitary  condition  has  been  found 
to  be  very  poor.  No  provision  is  made  for  the  cleanliness 
of  factories,  an  essential  to  good  health  as  well  as  to  fire 
protection.  No  provision  is  made  for  ventilation,  a  matter 
which  is  the  subject  of  numerous  administrative  orders  in 
other  States.  Not  only  is  the  ventilation  of  factories  left 
to  private  enterprise,  but  the  slight  provision  that  there  is 
for  toilets  does  not  provide  for  their  ventilation  and  factory 
toilets  are  very  generally  ventilated  through  the  work  rooms 
of  the  factory.  Only  in  Carroll  County21  is  there  any  pro- 
vision for  a  forced  ventilation  by  suction  fans  to  preserve 
the  workers  from  lung  diseases  brought  on  by  inhaling  dust 
and  noxious  gases.  To  be  entirely  fair,  the  law  requiring 
the  sprinkling  of  the  floors  of  shirt  factories  every  morn- 
ing22 should  be  mentioned  here,  but  the  relief  is  so  slight 
and  the  method  is  so  antiquated  that  this  narrowly  limited 
law  cannot  greatly  mitigate  the  indictment  of  Maryland. 
Finally,  if  we  omit  consideration  of  minor  requirements, 
there  is  in  Maryland  no  law  looking  to  the  proper  lighting 
of  factories;  and  the  employer  is  at  full  liberty  to  strain 
the  eyesight  of  his  workers  to  the  point  of  exhaustion.  Al- 
though I  have  not  made  a  thorough  investigation  at  first 
hand,  some  of  the  actual  conditions  described  I  have  myself 
observed;  and  if  some  first  hand  investigator  seeks  to  ex- 
tenuate these  failings  of  the  Maryland  law  by  maintaining 
that  actual  conditions  demonstrate  on  the  whole  that  Mary- 
land does  not  as  yet  need  regulatory  laws,  I  would  answer 
that  it  is  always  easier  to  prohibit  by  legislation  things 
which  are  not  in  existence  and  which  do  not  represent  as 
yet  any  vested  right.  Inasmuch,  moreover,  as  other  States 
have  had  to  cope  with  these  evils,  now  is  the  time  for  Mary- 
land to  legislate. 

In  decided  contrast  to  this  inefficient  phase  of  the  law  Is 

21  Laws  1894,  Ch.  202.    Applies  only  to  stone-grinding  mills. 

22  Code  1911,  Art.  43,  Sec.  102. 


235]  THE   CONDITIONS   OF   EMPLOYMENT  89 

the  recently  enacted  sanitary  inspection  law.23  The  act 
makes  minute  provision  for  the  regulation  of  every  place 
in  which  "  food  products  are  manufactured,  packed,  stored, 
deposited,  collected,  prepared,  produced  or  sold."24  In  ad- 
dition there  is  vested  in  the  State  Board  of  Health,  which 
is  entrusted  with  the  administration  of  the  law,  full  power 
to  promulgate,  "  from  time  to  time,  .  .  .  such  general  rules 
and  regulations  .  .  .  for  the  government  of  the  inspectors 
and  employees  of  the  board  as  may  be  necessary,"  provided 
it  gives  due  notice  of  these  orders  with  the  opportunity  of 
a  hearing  for  those  concerned.25  Since  the  administration 
of  the  law  is  vested  in  the  Board  of  Health,  its  purpose  is 
plainly  to  protect  the  health  of  the  community  rather  than 
to  benefit  the  workers,  but,  nevertheless,  improved  sur- 
roundings cannot  but  accrue  to  the  advantage  of  the  em- 
ployees. In  so  far,  however,  as  the  Board  of  Health  con- 
siders this  law  a  pure  health  measure,  its  orders  will  be 
and  in  fact  have  been  much  less  in  behalf  of  the  laborers 
than  if  the  administration  had  been  vested  in  the  labor 
department. 

The  specific  provisions  for  the  sanitary  norms  to  be  ap- 
plied to  the  various  food  factories  are  almost  ideal  in  their 
nature.26  It  is  first  enacted  that  all  of  the  rooms,  furniture 
and  implements  used  in  the  preparation  of  food  products 
shall  be  kept  in  "a  clean  and  sanitary  condition,"  unclean 
and  unsanitary  meaning  the  lack  of  protection  of  the  food 
itself  against  flies,  filth,  etc.,  the  failure  to  remove  all  dirt 
and  waste  product,  and  the  failure  to  keep  the  persons  of 
the  employees  clean.  It  might  have  been  provided  that  the 
side  walls  and  ceilings  should  be  regularly  lime-washed,  but 
in  the  absence  of  this  stipulation  it  is  to  be  expected  that 
the  Board  of  Health  will  issue  orders  to  fill  the  gap.  It  is 
further  enacted  that  "every  .  .  .  place  occupied  ...  for 

23  Laws  1914,  Ch.  678. 
2*  Ibid.,  Sec.  i. 


25  Ibid.i  Sec.  7. 

26  Ibid.,  Sec.  3,  Subsecs.  a-f. 


g/O  THE   LABOR  LAW   OF   MARYLAND  [236 

the  preparation,  etc.,  of  food  shall  have  convenient  toilet  or 
toilet  rooms  which  shall  be  kept  separate  from  the  rooms 
where  the  process  of  production,  etc.,  is  conducted,  and  all 
parts  of  such  toilet  rooms  shall  be  kept  clean."  Moreover, 
the  workers  are  forbidden  to  sleep  in  the  workroom  of  a 
bakeshop,  etc.,  or  in  the  kitchen  or  dining  room  of  a  hotel, 
restaurant  or  boarding  house ;  and  the  employer  is  forbid- 
den to  employ  any  worker  affected  with  a  communicable 
disease  unless  he  can  produce  a  certificate  from  the  Board 
of  Health  permitting  him  to  be  employed  in  such  a  place. 
Finally,  washrooms  are  ordered  to  be  constructed  in  these 
factories.  Further  stipulations  are  laid  down  for  canneries 
in  the  State,  but  these  are  largely  technical  and  do  not  add 
much  to  the  general  provisions. 

There  is  only  one  serious  omission  from  this  law :  cellar 
bakeries  are  not  prohibited.  It  is  obvious  that  "  a  cellar  is 
unfit  both  for  the  manufacture  of  food  stuffs  and  for  the 
habitation  of  workers.  There  can  be  no  natural  light  under 
the  most  favorable  conditions  in  a  cellar.  They  are  also 
very  difficult  places  to  ventilate  unless  a  mechanical  system 
is  installed,  which  is  out  of  the  question  in  the  ordinary 
small  bakery.  .  .  .  They  cannot  be  kept  as  clean  as  other 
parts  of  the  house,  for  they  are  semi-dark,  and  contain  most 
of  the  plumbing  pipes  and  fixtures.  They  are  also  the  nat- 
ural habitation  of  insects  and  rodents."27  Although  it  is 
true  that  conditions  in  Baltimore  bakeries  are  not  nearly  so 
bad  as  they  are  in  New  York  and,  in  fact,  it  has  been  said 
that  there  are  no  cellar  bakeries  in  this  city,28  the  absence 
of  the  evil,  as  has  been  contended  in  another  connection, 
constitutes  no  real  argument  against  sound  prophylactic 
legislation. 

The  Tenement  Law. — In  1914,  also,  Maryland  obtained 
perhaps  as  efficient  a  homework  or  tenement  law  as  is  pos- 

27  New   York   Factory   Investigation   Committee   Report,    Senate 
Documents  of  New  York,  1913,  vol.  13,  no.  36,  pt.  I,  p.  222. 

28  Dr.  Caspari  of  the  State  Board  of  Health,  who  has  charge  of 
the  administration  of  this  act  is  the  authority  for  this  statement. 


[237  THE   CONDITIONS  OF  EMPLOYMENT  9! 

sible.29  A  tenement  inspection  law  is  practically  always 
inadequate  because  of  the  impossibility  of  proper  inspection 
even  with  the  largest  corps  of  well-trained  inspectors.  A 
sufficient  corps  of  inspectors  may  perhaps  keep  the  tene- 
ments free  from  filth  and  disease,  but  an  absolutely  efficient 
administration  of  the  child  labor  law  or  any  other  law  affect- 
ing the  terms  of  labor  is  unattainable.  Investigations  in 
New  York  have  shown  that  children  too  young  to  be  sent 
to  school  were  put  to  work  helping  the  parent  and  that  chil- 
dren of  school  age  were  compelled  to  give  help  for  such 
unreasonable  hours  that  their  school  work  could  hardly  be 
of  any  practical  benefit.30  Moreover,  it  was  argued  by  some 
of  the  witnesses,  that  in  view  of  the  low  wages  paid  tene- 
ment workers  it  could  not  be  denied  that  some  manufactur- 
ers were  obtaining  an  unfair  advantage  in  free  rent  and  light 
at  the  ultimate  cost  of  the  State  in  broken-down  workers ; 
but,  pregnant  as  this  contention  may  be  in  forcefully  pre- 
senting some  of  the  evils  of  home  work,  it  cannot  be  said 
to  be  a  potent  argument  for  State  interference.  If  the  State 
determines  to  regulate  hours  of  labor,  wages  of  labor  and 
child  labor,  and  finds  it  impossible  to  do  so  while  tenement 
work-rooms  exist,  then,  granting  that  it  is  within  the  power 
of  the  State  to  undertake  this  regulation,  the  State  would 
have  the  right  to  prohibit  home  work.  The  health  of  the 
community  can  be  safeguarded  by  adequate  or  approxi- 
mately adequate  inspection  of  the  conditions  of  employ- 
ment, and  that  is  the  subject  of  this  chapter. 

The  act  provides  for  the  registration  of  every  factory, 
workshop,  or  mercantile  establishment  employing  five  or 
more  people  ;31  and  every  room  or  part  of  a  tenement  house 
which  is  to  be  used  for  manufacture  or  repair  work,  except, 
of  course,  the  personal  work  of  the  occupants,  must  first 
be  licensed  by  the  State  Board  of  Labor  and  Statistics.32  In 

29  Laws  1914,  Ch.  779. 

80  Conducted  by  the  Factory  Investigating  Committee. 

81  Code  1914,  Art.  27,  Sec.  264,  as  amended  by  Laws  1916,  Ch.  406. 

82  Ibid.,  Sec.  245. 


92  THE   LABOR  LAW   OF   MARYLAND  [238 

New  York  the  licensing  of  the  whole  tenement  as  a  unit 
has  been  found  more  efficient  than  the  licensing  of  each 
workshop  separately  since  it  interests  the  owner  of  the  tene- 
ment in  the  conditions  of  the  separate  workshops  and  makes 
an  additional  person  responsible  for  the  sanitary  conditions. 
This  is  perhaps  an  improvement  on  the  Maryland  law,  but 
not  of  fundamental  importance,  since,  as  it  is,  the  manu- 
facturer contracting  out  to  home  workers  is  also  compelled 
to  see  that  the  provisions  of  the  act  are  complied  with  in 
the  homes  to  which  he  sends  his  work.33  These  adminis- 
trative features  are  the  strong  points  of  the  law,  and  es- 
pecially so  when  coupled  with  the  minimum  requirement  of 
one  inspection  every  six  months — a  minimum,  however, 
much  below  comparative  efficiency,  but  expedient  for  the 
sake  of  economy. 

Although  below  the  most  exacting  standards,  the  sani- 
tary provisions  of  the  act,  if  conscientiously  enforced,  may 
raise  home  work  to  a  satisfactory  sanitary  level.  The  Board 
of  Labor  and  Statistics  has  powerful  means  in  its  hands  to 
enforce  these  provisions,  for  much  is  left  to  its  discretion 
in  granting  the  licenses  and  it  has  power  to  revoke  them 
upon  the  slightest  infringement  of  the  conditions  of  their 
grant.34  The  board  may  refuse  the  license  if  the  place  can- 
not show  a  clean  health  record.  If  the  health  record  be 
clean,  then  an  inspection  of  the  place  is  necessary;  and,  if 
the  board  through  its  inspectors  "  ascertain  that  such  room 
or  apartment  is  free  from  .  .  .  communicable  disease  and 
is  in  proper  sanitary  condition,  it  shall  grant  a  license  "  for 
the  place  to  be  used  by  members  of  the  family  only,  and 
that  only  to  the  number  of  one  worker  to  every  five  hun- 
dred cubic  feet  of  air  space.35  Though  the  New  York  com- 
mission recommended  more  stringent  sanitary  regulations 
than  these,  Massachusetts  has  practically  the  same  provi- 
sions as  has  Maryland.  While  not  ideal,  therefore,  the 
Maryland  provisions  at  least  may  be  said  to  be  adequate. 

38  Ibid.,  Sec.  247. 
"  Ibid.,  Sec.  248. 
85  Ibid.,  Sec.  245. 


239]  THE   CONDITIONS   OF   EMPLOYMENT  93 

In  actual  operation,  however,  the  law  is  not  so  satisfac- 
tory. The  final  determination  of  the  sanitary  condition  has 
been  left  in  the  hands  of  the  local  health  department,  for 
the  board  has  found  it  inexpedient  to  controvert  the  find- 
ings of  the  health  authorities  as  to  health  conditions.  The 
effect  of  this  has  been  that  practically  no  licenses  have  been 
refused  because  of  the  presence  of  communicable  diseases : 
the  health  authorities  rarely  find  any  evidence  of  such  dis- 
eases or,  if  any  is  found,  the  conditions  are  soon  corrected. 
It  is  hardly  within  the  scope  of  this  study  to  indict  the 
health  officials,  but  the  performance  of  their  part  in  the 
enforcement  of  the  law  has  been,  to  say  the  least,  very 
desultory. 


CHAPTER  V 
THE  TERMS  OF  EMPLOYMENT 

Foreword. — The  question  of  the  extent  to  which  the 
State  should  interfere  with  the  terms  of  employment  is  one 
of  the  most  acute  of  modern  legislative  problems.  In  gen- 
eral, it  may  be  said  that  as  the  State,  on  the  one  hand,  is  in 
most  cases  warranted  in  regulating  the  conditions  of  em- 
ployment, so,  on  the  other  hand,  in  most  cases  there  must 
be  actual  and  positive  cause  for  the  extension  of  State  activ- 
ity to  the  control  of  the  terms  of  employment.  In  general, 
the  problem  of  the  hours  and  wages  of  employment  should 
be  solved  by  the  bargaining  of  the  wage-earner  and  the  em- 
ployer. 

The  extent  to  which  the  State  should  interfere  with  the 
terms  of  employment  is,  of  course,  one  of  the  questions  of 
the  science  of  legislation,  and  it  should  be  solved  according 
to  the  norms  and  maxims  of  that  science.  But  it  is  practi- 
cally impossible  for  a  student  of  American  government  to 
consider  legislative  problems  solely  in  the  light  of  the  prin- 
ciples of  legislation.  If  he  could  do  so,  his  task  would  be 
comparatively  simple.  An  almost  religious  regard  for  the 
law  of  the  Constitution  has  so  imbedded  itself  in  the  legal 
thought  of  the  United  States  that  to  think  of  framing  an 
enactment  without  scrupulous  respect  for  its  constitutional- 
ity would  be  unpardonable  sacrilege.  It  is  this  which  ac- 
counts for  the  obvious  and  deplorable  lack  of  consistency 
and  scheme  in  the  labor  legislation  of  every  State.  The 
grossest  inconsistency  is  apparent  in  the  enactments  con- 
cerning labor  unions  and  the  terms  of  the  contract  of  em- 
ployment. 

In  attempting  to  outline  an  ideal  and  consistent  scheme 
of  legislation,  I  shall  attempt  to  prove  in  a  subsequent  chap- 

94 


THE  TERMS   OF   EMPLOYMENT  95 

ter  that  legislation  regulating  the  terms  of  employment  is 
only  justified  as  a  temporary  expedient.  Labor  legislation, 
as  has  been  so  often  iterated,  is  a  means  of  equalizing  the 
bargaining  power  of  labor  and  capital,  but  the  greatest 
equalizer,  it  will  be  shown,  is  the  union.  Until  the  ideal  of 
complete  unionization  is  attained,  State  interference  with 
the  terms  of  employment  is  justified.  The  courts  have  up- 
held legislation  in  respect  to  the  hours  and  wages  of  em- 
ployment of  women  and  children,  but  have  quite  as  unani- 
mously overthrown  similar  legislation  for  unorganized 
workingmen  unless  the  occupation  is  especially  danger- 
ous. They  have  thus  established  a  principle  of  American 
legislation,  but  a  principle  which  is  unsound.  It  seems  to 
be  based  upon  two  fundamental  conceptions.  In  the  first 
place,  women  and  children  because  of  their  weaker  nature 
have  all  through  the  common  law  been  considered  just  re- 
cipients of  the  protection  of  the  law.  "  The  courts  have, 
therefore,  always  rather  welcomed1  legislation  delimiting 
the  employment  of  women  and  children.  Their  antagonism 
to  legislation  for  adult  males,  however,  is  unjustified,  for, 
although  the  weakness  of  women  and  children  does  entitle 
them  to  additional  protection  from  the  State  against  undue 
influence  and  fraud,  the  unorganized  male  laborer  is  in  as 
unfair  a  position  in  making  a  wage  contract  with  the  aver- 
age employer  as  the  weakest  woman.  Mental  strength  has 
little  effect  against  a  dominating  force.  In. the  second  place, 
the  courts  in  upholding  labor  legislation  of  this  kind  put  it 
most  often  in  the  rubric  of  health  laws.  Of  course,  it  is 
true  that  the  physical  condition  of  women  and  children  is 
less  resistant  than  that  of  men,  and,  moreover,  it  is  easy  to 
argue  that  the  welfare  of  the  community  is  more  strictly 
connected  with  the  health  of  women  and  children  than  with 
that  of  men.  But  this  is  largely  a  matter  of  degree  and 
hardly  the  occasion  for  such  a  strict  drawing  of  constitu- 
tional lines.  A  needless  inconsistency  is  the  result. 

1 1  think  that  I  am  justified  in  the  use  of  this  word  in  view  of  the 
decision  in  Bosley  v.  McLoughlin,  236  U.  S.  385. 


96  THE   LABOR   LAW  OF   MARYLAND  [242 

If  to  this  inconsistency  is  added  the  pressure  of  all  kinds 
of  reform  organizations  for  every  conceivable  limitation  of 
the  terms  of  labor  and  the  cheap  politics  displayed  by  can- 
didates competing  for  the  vote  of  the  laboring  class,  the 
possibilities  of  a  shapeless  system  of  labor  legislation  seem 
of  limitless  magnitude.  This  shapelessness  has  been  more 
than  achieved.  Instead  of  the  almost  total  absence  of  leg- 
islation regulating  hours  and  wages  of  labor  which  would 
be  the  case  under  ideal  conditions,  the  statutes  of  the  aver- 
age State  are  an  enervating  hodge-podge.  Antiquated  and 
useless  legislation  is  left  on  the  books  to  the  confusion  of 
the  lawyer  and  student;  conflicting  laws  are  enacted  with- 
out taking  the  trouble  to  repeal  the  earlier  laws;  criminal 
laws  without  penalties  are  set  forth  as  sops  to  some  now 
forgotten  reform  movement;  and  high  sounding  laws  with 
fatal  exceptions  are  in  endless  abundance.  This  is  a  con- 
cise and  exact  description  of  the  legislation  of  Maryland 
in  spite  of  some  recent  efforts  of  the  legislators.  There  is 
absolutely  no  unity  or  system  present.  It  must  not  be  un- 
derstood, however,  that  Maryland  is  unique  in  this  respect. 
Except  for  those  States,  of  which  Wisconsin  is  the  fore- 
most example,  which  have  practically  repealed  all  their  pre- 
vious labor  law  and  left  to  a  commission  the  evolution  of  a 
new  system,  every  State  of  the  Union  is  equally  guilty. 
Even  New  York,  which  has  recently  adopted  almost  an  en- 
tire new  code  of  labor  legislation  has  been  remiss  in  failing 
to  repeal  the  earlier  law.  But  for  an  estimate  of  the  status 
of  the  laborer  in  Maryland,  some  study  of  this  phase  of  the 
law  is  necessary.  For  the  purposes  of  this  chapter  I  have, 
therefore,  arranged  the  laws  under  three  heads :  first,  those 
prohibiting  the  employment  of  certain  classes  in  specified 
occupations;  second,  those  regulating  the  hours  of  labor; 
and,  third,  those  regulating  the  wages  of  labor. 

Prohibitions  of  Employment. — The  absolute  prohibitions 
contained  in  the  Maryland  labor  law  with  the  two  excep- 
tions referring  to  the  employment  of  women  as  barmaids2 

2  Code  Public  Local  Laws  1888,  Art.  13,  Sees.  195-196. 


243]  THE   TERMS   OF   EMPLOYMENT  97 

and  as  waitresses  in  places  of  amusement3  are  all  confined 
to  child  labor.  The  laws  forbidding  absolutely  the  use  of 
dangerous  materials  or  methods  in  any  occupation  have  ob- 
tained no  foothold  in  this  State.  Indeed,  there  are  few 
laws  of  this  kind  in  the  country,  only  one,  the  federal  pro- 
hibitive tax  on  the  phosphorous  matchmaking  industry, 
being  a  typical  example.  An  anti-homework  law  might  be 
desirable.  This  type  of  legislation  is  much  more  effective 
than  the  regulatory  laws  described  in  the  last  chapter,  to 
which  they  are  closely  related,  but  the  American  tendency 
is  towards  regulation  rather  than  absolute  prohibition. 

The  usual  prohibitions  to  be  found  in  any  State,  then, 
refer  to  child  labor ;  the  education  of  the  child  and  the  pro- 
tection of  the  young  person,  as  he  is  technically  called,  being 
the  ends  of  the  law.  Thus  in  Maryland  no  minor  under 
twenty-one  years  of  age  is  permitted  to  work  in  or  in  con- 
nection with  any  place  where  spirituous  liquors  are  sold.* 
It  seems  exceedingly  doubtful  whether  this  provision  is 
strictly  enforced  for  the  difficulties  of  administration  are 
obvious.  Prohibition  reform  would,  of  course,  be  more  effi- 
cient ;  and  even  putting  the  enforcement  in  the  hands  of  the 
Liquor  License  Board  might  aid  in  increasing  the  effective- 
ness of  the  law. 

Children  under  the  age  of  eighteen  years,  as  in  most 
other  industrial  States,  are  forbidden  to  work  in  or  about 
"  blast  furnaces,  docks  or  wharves ;  or  in  the  outside  erec- 
tion and  repair  of  electric  wires ;  in  the  running  or  man- 
agement of  elevators,  lifts  or  hoisting  machines  or  dyna- 
mos; in  oiling  or  cleaning  machinery  in  motion;  ...  at 
switch  tending,  gate  tending,  track  repairing  or  as  brake- 
men,  firemen,  engineers,  etc.,  upon  railroads ;  ...  or  in  or 
about  establishments,  where  .  .  .  high  or  dangerous  explo- 
sives are  manufactured,  compounded  or  stored  .  .  ."  or  in 

8  Code  1914,  Art.  27,  Sees.  442-443. 

*Laws  1912,  Ch.  731,  Sec.  22  (to  be  Art.  100  of  Code);  Code 
1911,  Art.  56,  Sec.  98. 


98  THE   LABOR  LAW   OF   MARYLAND  [244 

other  like  occupations  wherein  their  immaturity  would  ren- 
der them  inefficient.5 

Children  under  sixteen  years  of  age  are  rigidly  circum- 
scribed in  their  employment.  They  are  forbidden  to  be 
employed  around  dangerous  machines  as  circular  or  band 
saws,  picker  machines  or  machines  used  in  picking  wool, 
cotton  or  any  other  material,  job  or  cylinder  printing 
presses  operated  by  machinery,  stamping  machines  and 
numerous  others  specified  at  great  length.  They  are  not 
permitted  to  work  upon  any  steam,  electric  or  hydraulic 
railway  or  on  any  machinery  operated  by  power  other  than 
hand  or  foot  power,  or  upon  any  vessel  or  boat  engaged  in 
navigation  or  commerce.  Occupations  wherein  dangerous 
or  poisonous  acids  are  used  are  closed  to  them,  as  is  min- 
ing and  the  allied  occupation  of  tunneling.  They  are  for- 
bidden to  perform  in  any  concert  hall  or  playhouse  in  con- 
nection with  any  professional  theatrical  performance,  ex- 
hibition or  show.6 

There  is  also  a  prohibition  of  the  employment  of  females 
under  sixteen  where  such  employment  compels  them  to  re- 
main constantly  standing.7  This  is  really  more  of  a  regu- 
lation of  the  conditions  than  of  the  terms  of  employment; 
and,  though  somewhat  vague,  it  is  fundamentally  an  exem- 
plary piece  of  legislation  in  which  Maryland  seems  to  have 
established  a  precedence.  Moreover,  no  child  under  six- 
teen can  be  employed  in  any  occupation  until  he  has  ob- 
tained a  permit  from  the  Bureau  of  Statistics  in  Baltimore 
City  or  from  the  superintendent  of  schools  in  a  county. 
These  employment  permits  or  certificates  are  of  two  classes, 
general  and  vacation  employment  certificates,  and  are  is- 
sued only  on  the  conditions  of  a  satisfactory  school  record, 
of  a  favorable  report  from  a  competent  physician,  and  evi- 
dence that  the  child  is  of  legal  age  to  work  in  the  desired 

6  Laws  1912,  Ch.  731,  Sec.  21. 

6  Laws  1912,  Ch.  731,  Sees.  7-8,  as  amended  by  Laws  1916,  Ch.  222, 
and  see  Code  1914,  Art.  27,  Sec.  346. 

7  Laws  1916,  Ch.  222,  Sec.  23. 


245]  THE  TERMS  OF  EMPLOYMENT  99 

occupation.8  The  granting  of  these  certificates  is  regulated 
moreover  by  stringent  administrative  provisions.  Similar 
to  these  certificates,  but  with  the  necessary  differences,  are 
the  badges  granted  to  boys  between  the  ages  of  twelve  and 
sixteen  to  sell  papers  and  periodicals  on  the  street  during 
daylight.9 

Subject  to  these  stipulations  and  exceptions,  it  is  legal  in 
Maryland  to  employ  children  above  the  age  of  fourteen. 
Children  under  fourteen  are  forbidden  to  be  employed  "  in, 
about  or  in  connection  with  any  mill,  factory,  mechanical 
establishment,  tenement  house,  .  .  .  office  building,  .  .  . 
public  stable,  garage  or  in  any  mercantile  establishment 
.  .  .  ,  place  of  amusement,  club,  etc.,"  in  short,  in  most 
occupations.10  The  fourteen  year  age  limit  is  also  estab- 
lished to  a  certain  degree  by  prohibiting  the  employment 
under  that  age  during  school  hours.11  There  are,  however, 
in  the  Maryland  law  two  provisions  allowing  the  employ- 
ment outside  of  school  hours  of  children  above  the  age  of 
twelve  in  "canning  or  packing  establishments,"12  and  of 
males  above  the  age  of  twelve  in  the  sale  of  periodicals  and 
newspapers  on  the  streets.  Boys  above  ten  may  with  a 
permit  distribute  papers  on  a  regular  route  between  the 
hours  of  3 130  and  5  too  p.m.13  If  the  twelve  year  mini- 
mum is  enforced  in  canneries  and  allied  occupations,  Mary- 
land children  are  better  protected  than  those  in  most  other 
canning  States,  in  New  York,  at  least,  it  having  been  found 
practically  impossible  to  enforce  a  fourteen  year  minimum.14 

On  the  whole,  this  rubric  of  the  Maryland  labor  law  at- 
tains as  high  a  standard  as  that  set  anywhere  in  the  coun- 
try. The  Child  Labor  Law  is  a  recent  enactment  and  seems 

8  Laws  1912,  Ch.  731,  Sec.  gS. 

9  Ibid.,  Sees.  27-33. 

10  Laws  1912,  Ch.  731,  Sec.  4,  as  amended  by  Acts  1916,  Sec.  222. 

11  Laws  1912,  Ch.  731,  Sec.  6;  Laws  1912,  Ch.  173. 

12  Laws  1912,  Ch.  731,  Sec.  5. 

13  Laws  1912,  Ch.  731,  Sec.  26,  as  finally  amended  by  Laws  1916, 
Ch.  222. 

14  See  Annual  Report  of  Commissioner  of  Labor,  New  York,  1914, 
P.  135- 


IOO  THE   LABOR  LAW   OF   MARYLAND  [246 

to  have  been  drafted  in  a  scientific  and  careful  manner,  fol- 
lowing rather  closely  the  laws  of  New  York  and  Massachu- 
setts, which  mark  a  high  plane  in  the  conservative  reform 
law  of  this  country.  There  is,  however,  one  prohibition 
omitted  in  the  Maryland  labor  law  which  experts  have  come 
to  consider  absolutely  necessary.  Most  European  countries 
and  four  American  States,  Connecticut,  Massachusetts, 
New  York  and  Vermont,  forbid  the  employment  of  women 
for  certain  periods  before  and  after  childbirth.  There  is  no 
doubt  of  the  constitutionality  of  such  a  law,  for  it  has  been 
amply  demonstrated  that  the  community  suffers  from  the 
high  rate  of  mortality  and  morbidity  of  babies  who  fail  to 
receive  sufficient  care  from  their  mothers.  Such  a  law,  how- 
ever, would  involve  a  considerable  step  towards  communism, 
especially  as  the  perfected  plan  would  call  for  some  kind 
of  aid  from  the  State  during  the  period  of  enforced  rest.15 

Hours. — The  regulation  of  the  hours  of  labor  has  caused 
the  legislators  of  the  last  quarter  of  a  century  the  greatest 
difficulty.  The  exact  limit  of  their  power  has  not  been 
clearly  defined,  and  they  can  never  be  sure  that  their 
enactments  compelled  by  the  clamors  of  reformers,  eco- 
nomic and  political,  will  be  upheld  by  the  courts.  It  is  in 
fact  within  this  rubric  of  the  labor  law  that  the  attempt  is 
sometimes  made  to  limit  the  police  power  of  the  State. 
Somewhere  a  law  ceases  to  be  an  exercise  of  the  police 
power  and  becomes  a  taking  of  property  without  due  proc- 
ess of  law.  The  doctrine  of  reasonableness  has  been  formu- 
lated by  the  courts,  but  this  doctrine  hardly  gives  any  true 
clue  to  the  problem.  It  is  best  to  say  that  there  is  much 
hopeless  conflict  between  the  courts  and  that  in  the  end  each 
law  must  be  considered  on  its  own  merits. 

The  economic  argument  for  restricting  the  hours  of  labor 
has  been  so  often  iterated  and  reiterated  that  it  has  become 

15  The  Italian  plan  raises  the  fund  for  the  care  of  the  indigent 
mothers  by  taxing  each  woman  of  child-bearing  age  employed  in  any 
industry  thirteen  cents  a  month,  each  employer  seven  cents  per 
month  per  woman  of  that  age  employed  by  him,  and  by  an  addi- 
tional seven  cents  per  woman  contributed  by  the  state. 


247]  THE  TERMS  OF  EMPLOYMENT  IOI 


shopworn  ;  and  it  will  not  be  worth  while  to  set  it  forth  at 
length.  The  arguments  of  the  economists  may  well  be  ac- 
cepted at  their  face  value,  but  must  then  be  considered  from 
the  viewpoint  of  legislation.  The  economic  argument  runs 
something  like  this:  Long  hours  are  physically  injurious. 
Long  hours  stultify  the  intellectual  growth  of  the  individual 
because  of  lack  of  time  for  self  -enlightenment.  Long  hours 
lead  to  immorality  and  excess  in  recreation.  Long  hours 
tend  to  lessen  the  influence  of  family  life  and  ultimately  to 
destroy  it.  The  shortening  of  hours  more  than  pays  for 
itself  in  increased  efficiency.16  And  then,  having  heaped  up 
facts,  the  economist  will  emphasize  one  of  them,  the  physi- 
cal deterioration  or  the  intellectual  stultification,  depending 
on  whether  the  law  in  question  bears  upon  women  or  chil- 
dren. The  courts  accept  this  reasoning  and  uphold  hours- 
of-lafoor  laws  for  women  and  children.  When  a  law  limit- 
ing the  hours  of  labor  of  men  is  presented  to  them,  the 
courts  have  generally  refused  to  sanction  it,  though  the 
economic  argument  for  it  is  precisely  the  same.  There  is 
here  an  inconsistency  due  to  the  lack  of  a  complete  scheme 
or  philosophy  of  labor  legislation. 

The  limitations  on  the  hours  of  labor  of  children  in  Mary- 
land were  not  of  a  very  high  standard  until  1916.  Prior  to 
that  there  was,  except  for  the  two  provisions  aimed  at  keep- 
ing messengers  and  newsboys  off  the  streets  at  night,17  only 
a  general  prohibition  that  no  child  under  sixteen  should 
labor  more  than  ten  hours  a  day  in  any  manufacturing  busi- 
ness in  the  State  or  in  any  mercantile  establishment  in  Bal- 
timore.18 Now  there  is  a  strict  prohibition  of  labor  of  chil- 
dren under  sixteen  in  enumerated  occupations,  including 
practically  all  except  canning  and  domestic  labor,  for  more 
than  six  days  in  any  one  week,  or  more  than  forty-eight 

16  For  a  typical  example,  see  the  brief  prepared  by  Mr.  Louis 
Brandeis   for   the   Consumers'   League   in   Muller  v.   Oregon.  208 
U.  S.  412. 

17  Laws  1912,  Ch.  731,  Sees.  24-32,  and  see  also  Code  1911,  Art 
23,  Sec.  375- 

18  Code  1914,  Art  27,  Sec.  239  ;  Laws  1892,  Ch.  443. 


IO2  THE   LABOR   LAW   OF   MARYLAND  [248 

hours  during  that  time,  or  more  than  eight  hours  in  any  one 
day,  or  between  the  hours  of  seven  in  the  evening  and  seven 
in  the  morning.  Moreover,  the  mere  "presence  of  such 
child  in  any  establishment  shall  be  prima  facie  evidence  of 
its  employment."19  This  is  an  almost  ideal  law,  the  excep- 
tion of  canning  and  domestic  labor  being  necessitated  by 
expediency.  The  prohibition  of  night  work  and  the  final 
administrative  provision  merit  special  attention.  Minors 
above  sixteen  are  not  specially  legislated  for  in  Maryland 
and  are  included  in  the  legislation  for  adults. 

The  maximum  legal  extent  of  employment  for  women  in 
Maryland  is  ten  hours  in  any  one  day  and  sixty  hours  in  a 
week.20  This  law  was  enacted  in  1912  after  a  bitter  strug- 
gle, but,  as  it  stands  now  on  our  statute  book,  Maryland 
ranks  about  on  the  level  with  most  other  States  of  the  coun- 
try in  this  respect.  There  are,  however,  two  exceptions  in 
the  Maryland  act  which  are  interesting.  The  first  exception 
exempts  from  the  operation  of  the  law  females  employed 
in  the  canning  or  preserving  or  preparation  for  canning  or 
preserving  of  perishable  fruits  and  vegetables.  Although 
this  exception  has  been  bitterly  assailed  by  the  reform 
forces  and  although  it  is  illogical  and  perhaps  unsocial,  yet 
it  seems  perfectly  justified  by  expediency.  New  York, 
which  has  enacted  a  ten-hour  law  applying  to  canneries, 
has  found  it  practically  impossible  to  enforce  it,  though  the 
labor  commissioner  has  hopes  of  slow  education  up  to  the 
standard.21  Some  sort  of  limitation  of  hours  in  canneries 
is  needed — perhaps  a  graduated  scale  over  several  years 
would  be  feasible — but  no  law  is  better  than  an  unenforced 
and  un  en  forcible  law.  The  other  exception  allows  twelve 
hours'  work  on  Saturdays  and  six  days  preceding  Christ- 
mas in  retail  mercantile  establishments  outside  the  City  of 
Baltimore,  provided  that  there  are  two  periods  of  rest  on 

19  Laws  1916,  Ch.  222,  Sec.  22A. 

20  Laws  1912,  Ch.  79,  as  amended  by  Laws  1916,  Ch.  147. 

21  See  Report  of  New  York  Commissioner  of  Labor  for  1914, 
p.  133  ff- 


249]  THE  TERMS  OF  EMPLOYMENT 

those  days  and  provided  also  that  the  women  in  these  estab- 
lishments work  no  more  than  nine  hours  a  day  during  the 
remainder  of  the  year.  Here  again  the  exception  is  not 
logically  sound,  but  is  dictated  by  administrative  expedi- 
ency. New  York  has  a  similar  exception. 

There  is  no  prohibition  of  night  work  for  women,  that 
is,  no  hours  between  which  women  are  not  allowed  to  labor ; 
only  instead  of  ten  hours  per  day  being  the  legal  limit  a 
shorter  day  of  eight  hours  is  stipulated.  This  is  a  serious 
omission.  Night  work  practically  deprives  women  of  any 
but  the  most  meager  period  of  rest  on  account  of  the  insist- 
ence of  household  duties  during  the  day  when  the  worker 
is  supposed  to  be  sleeping.  Moreover,  night  work  makes 
the  complete  and  efficient  enforcement  of  the  legal  day  al- 
most impossible,  for  unless  certain  opening  and  closing 
hours  are  fixed,  an  inspector  cannot  unearth  violations  ex- 
cept by  spending  all  his  time  in  one  factory  checking  up  the 
various  women  as  they  come  in  and  leave.  Both  New  York 
and  Massachusetts  prohibit  night  work  for  women. 

The  limitations  put  upon  the  hours  of  labor  of  men  are 
more  in  the  nature  of  norms  than  absolute  regulations. 
This  is  what  would  be  expected.  Thus  eight  hours  is  the 
legal  day  for  employees  of  the  City  of  Baltimore  and  for 
employees  of  contractors  engaged  in  public  work.22  There 
is  an  exception  allowing  overtime  for  the  protection  of  life 
and  property,  an  exception  which  can  easily  be  stretched  to 
cover  ordinary  overtime.  Again,  there  is  the  provision  that 
ten  hours  shall  be  the  legal  day  in  cotton  and  woolen  manu- 
factories23 and  in  mines  in  Alleghany  and  Garrett  counties,2* 
but  any  adult  male  may  contract  to  work  longer.  However, 
for  public  safety,  street  car  employees55  and  train  dispatch- 
ers on  a  railroad  employing  the  block  system26  are  limited 
to  twelve  and  eight  hours  a  day,  respectively.  These  laws 

22  Laws  1910,  Ch.  94.    See  also  Laws  1916,  Ch.  134. 

23  Code  1911,  Art.  100,  Sees.  1-2. 

24  Code  Public  Local  Laws  1888,  Art.  12,  Sec.  165 ;  Art.  i,  Sec.  194. 

25  Baltimore  City  Charter  1915,  Sees.  793-5. 
28  Code  1911,  Art.  23,  Sec.  323. 


IO4  THE   LABOR   LAW   OF   MARYLAND  [250 

are  not  important  in  a  general  estimate  of  labor  conditions. 
The  public-works  law  does  give  some  evidence  of  the 
strength  of  labor  as  a  political  force  and  the  ineffective 
laws  display  a  further  attempt  of  the  legislature,  bootless 
this  time,  to  curry  favor  with  the  workingmen,  but  neither 
are  particularly  instructive  examples  of  State  activity. 

Wages. — When  we  come  to  consider  the  third  kind  of 
legislation  regulating  the  terms  of  employment,  laws  with 
regard  to  the  wages  of  labor,  an  entirely  new  field  is  opened 
to  the  investigator.  There  are,  of  course,  the  enactments 
protecting  the  laborer  against  the  fraud  and  delay  of  the 
employer,  but  what  is  most  interesting  to  the  student  of  leg- 
islation is  the  recent  tendency  of  States  to  set  minimum 
wages  for  various  classes  of  workers.  This  is  a  reversion 
to  the  Middle  Ages  practice  of  setting  a  "  fair  and  just " 
wage  with  the  significant  substitution  of  a  legal  minimum 
for  a  legally  absolute  wage.  The  distinction  certainly  is 
significant,  but  both  the  "fair  and  just"  and  the  minimum 
wage  are  enactments  of  a  very  paternalistic  government. 

Recognizing  "  that  not  only  hours  and  working  conditions 
where  there  is  inequality  of  bargaining,  properly  concern  the 
state,  but  that  the  question  of  wages  also  has  a  direct  con- 
nection with  the  welfare  of  the  worker,  and  therefore  of  the 
public,"  a  score  of  states,  American  and  foreign,  have  en- 
acted minimum  wage  laws.  "Wages,"  it  is  further  stated 
by  this  advocate  of  these  laws,  "  have  a  decided  bearing  on 
the  health  of  the  employees.  The  workers  who  have  suffi- 
cient nourishing  food  and  who  live  under  healthful  condi- 
tions are  more  resistant  to  the  evil  effects  of  working  con- 
ditions. Living  conditions  are  dependent  to  a  very  large 
extent  upon  working  conditions,  and  a  betterment  of  hours 
and  wages  means  a  betterment  of  the  mode  of  living  and 
therefore  of  the  efficiency  of  the  worker."27  The  argument 
is  incontestable  if  health  is  the  standard  according  to  which 
the  state  should  guarantee  every  worker  a  "living  wage," 

27  Report  of  Industrial  Commission  of  Wisconsin  for  Two  Years 
Ending  June  30,  1914,  p.  58. 


THE   TERMS   OF   EMPLOYMENT  IO5 

the  protests  of  the  capitalists  to  the  contrary  notwithstand- 
ing; but  if  the  goal  of  state  regulation  is  to  establish  equal- 
ity of  bargaining  power,  if  the  aim  of  state  interference  is 
to  remedy  causes,  not  symptoms,  then  minimum  wage  leg- 
islation seems  beyond  the  limits  of  state  activity,  although 
perhaps  a  useful  temporary  expedient.  Maryland  has  no 
minimum  wage  law,  and,  according  to  the  doctrines  which 
are  advocated  in  this  study,  her  stand  is  correct. 

All  of  the  laws,  of  course,  apply  only  to  females  and 
minors,  for  the  same  reasons  that  all  other  laws  relating  to 
the  terms  of  employment  are  restricted  to  them.  Most  of 
the  enactments  are  general  in  their  wording,  leaving  to  ad- 
ministrative boards  the  interpretation  of  the  general  terms. 
"  Every  wage  paid  or  agreed  to  be  paid  by  an  employer  to 
any  female  or  minor  employee  .  .  .  shall  be  not  less  than 
a  living  wage"  except  that  incompetents  may  be  granted 
licenses  to  work  at  lower  rates,  says  tne  Wisconsin  law ; 
and  a  " '  living  wage '  shall  mean  compensation  .  .  .  suffi- 
cient to  enable  the  employee  ...  to  maintain  himself  or 
herself "  in  "  reasonable  comfort,  reasonable  well-being, 
decency  and  moral  well-being."28  To  administer  these  laws 
steps  are  taken  very  similar  to  those  described  in  the  last 
chapter  in  connection  with  the  commission  form  of  labor 
legislation.  Some  kind  of  commission  is  always  given  the 
administration  of  the  law.  If  the  commission  has  any  rea- 
son to  believe  that  the  wages  paid  females  or  minors  in  any 
industry  or  trade  are  unreasonably  low  or  if  any  individ- 
ual or  organization  complains  to  the  commission  that  such 
conditions  exist,  the  commission  will  begin  an  investigation 
into  the  wage  conditions  in  that  industry.  This  preliminary 
investigation  is  usually  ex  parte  and  is  in  the  nature  of  an 
inquest  by  the  grand  jury.  If  the  commission  decides  that 
there  is  reason  to  believe  that  there  is  some  truth  in  these 
suspicions,  it  appoints  a  board  composed  of  employees  and 
employers  with  sometimes  a  representative  of  the  public  to 

28  Wisconsin  Acts  1913,  Ch.  712,  Sec.  1729,  s-i,  (4)  and  (5)  ;  2,  7. 


IO6  THE   LABOR   LAW   OF   MARYLAND 

investigate  thoroughly  and  determine  on  a  living  wage. 
This  board  usually  has  power  to  summon  and  pay  witnesses 
and  every  one  interested  may  appear.  The  minimum  de- 
cided upon,  either  per  day,  per  week  or  by  the  piece,  ac- 
cording to  the  industry,  is  then  reported  back  to  the  govern- 
ment commission,  before  whom  may  appear  any  complain- 
ants who  are  aggrieved  at  the  board's  findings.  When  the 
legal  minimum  is  finally  proclaimed,  all  employers  in  that 
industry  must  conform  to  the  rulings  of  the  commission. 
In  some  States,  however,  for  example,  Massachusetts,29  the 
penalty  for  disobedience  is  merely  uncomfortable  publicity. 
If  the  minimum  wage  is  really  well  founded  such  a  sanc- 
tion is  sufficient. 

It  is  obvious  that  under  a  minimum  wage  law  the  em- 
ployer is  not  obliged  to  pay  for  what  he  does  not  receive, 
he  must  only  pay  a  little  more  than  he  has  been  accustomed 
to  pay.  He  is  not  obliged  to  pay  a  piece-worker  so  much 
per  week  no  matter  how  much  she  may  loaf  during  the 
week.  He  is  not  obliged  to  pay  the  unskilled  as  much  as 
the  skilled.  The  delinquent  is  allowed  to  work  for  less  than 
the  competent  and  children  for  less  than  adults.  Most  in- 
dustries will  not  be  affected  by  the  legal  minimum — wages 
there  are  above  it — and  those  affected  are  expected  to  get 
more  work  for  the  higher  wages  through  the  increased  ef- 
ficiency of  the  workers.  The  minimum  wage  laws  have 
been  evolved  to  a  high  degree  of  efficiency  in  their  details. 
Arguments  against  them  must  attack  the  fundamentals,  not 
the  superstructure. 

Of  an  entirely  different  nature  from  the  minimum  wage 
laws  are  those  enactments  regulating  the  wage  agreements 
of  adult  men ;  for  though  these  laws  are  general  and  apply 
to  all  workers,  it  is  because  they  include  men  that  new  leg- 
islative and  constitutional  principles  are  involved.  This 
legislation  is  justified  on  the  ground  that  it  is  aimed  pri- 
marily at  fraud.  The  employer  on  account  of  his  position 

29  Massachusetts  Acts  1912,  Ch.  706,  as  amended  by  Acts  1914, 
Ch.  368. 


253]  THE   TERMS   OF   EMPLOYMENT  IO/ 

as  trustee  for  the  earned  but  unpaid  wages  of  his  employ- 
ees is  in  such  a  superior  position  that  he  is  able,  if  he  wishes, 
to  exercise  the  most  fraudulent  compulsion  upon  the  work- 
ers. It  is  at  this  evil  that  this  last  class  of  laws  affecting 
the  terms  of  labor  is  aimed.  An  example,  though  a  rather 
extreme  example,  of  the  protection  afforded  by  the  State 
is  the  law  forbidding  railroad  companies  doing  business 
within  the  State  to  withhold  any  part  of  the  wages  of  its 
employees  for  the  benefit  of  any  relief  association  or  the 
members  thereof.30  Most  of  the  laws,  however,  are  aimed 
at  the  insidious  truck  system,  as  it  is  called,  which  has  now 
fortunately  become  practically  extinct  in  the  eastern  sections 
of  the  country.31 

The  truck  system  has  largely  depended  upon  the  fact 
that  nature  is  so  perverse  as  to  establish  her  most  necessary 
metallic  resources  in  out-of-the-way  places.  Mining  com- 
munities have  always  been  on  the  economic  frontier  of  civ- 
ilization. A  not  unusual  occurrence  is  the  springing  up  of 
a  full-sized  town  out  of  an  uncultivated  waste.  In  these 
cases  the  mining  company  is  generally  the  owner  of  the 
town,  the  land,  the  homes  and  the  public  buildings.  If  not 
thus  far  centralized,  at  least  the  source  of  the  food  supply 
is  in  the  hands  of  the  mining  company.  At  first  the  com- 
pany is  performing  a  real  economic  service  in  establishing 
the  company  store,  and  it  is  a  real  benefit  to  the  workers 
to  have  a  steady  source  from  which  to  purchase  their  neces- 
sities instead  of  having  to  rely  on  the  possibility  of  an  itin- 
erant huckster.  This  is  the  good  side  of  the  truck  system ; 
and,  perhaps,  in  the  right  hands,  the  company  store  might 
remain  a  benefit  to  the  laborers,  although  the  monopolistic 
weapons  of  the  shop  are  of  a  really  dangerous  nature.  But 

80  Code  191 1,  Art.  23,  Sec.  315. 

81  Most  of  the  information  about  the  truck  system  has  been  taken 
from  the  Report  of  the  Commissioners  Appointed  to  Inquire  into 
the  Truck  System,  1871.    The  general  features  of  the  system  are  so 
constant  that,  it  is  believed,  nothing  has  been  lost  by  using  an  Eng- 
lish instead  of  an  American   source,  especially  since  the  English 
source  is  generally  available  and  compact. 


IO8  THE   LABOR   LAW   OF    MARYLAND  [254 

the  truck  system  is  usually  attended  by  much  more  sinister 
forces. 

The  truck  system  is  usually  sustained  by  the  maintain- 
ance  of  long  intervals  between  pay  days,  although  in  Scot- 
land it  was  found  to  exist  where  the  interval  was  only  two 
weeks.  Now  the  miners  as  a  class  earn  just  about  the  mar- 
ginal subsistence  wages  and  have  very  little  chance  to  be 
provident.  If  the  employee  does  not  begin  his  employment 
under  the  necessity  of  obtaining  credit,  he  has  many  chances 
of  acquiring  this  unenviable  position.  The  company  store 
avails  itself  of  this  opportunity  in  two  ways.  Sometimes 
it  merely  extends  credit  to  the  laborer,  establishing  a  sort 
of  lien  on  his  accruing  wages  and  collecting  this  lien  by  a 
system  of  bookkeeping  in  the  company's  office  or  by  setting 
up  a  collection  office  so  close  to  the  paymaster's  window 
that  escape  from  its  clutches  is  impossible.  Its  credits  are 
therefore  much  safer  than  those  of  any  chance  competitor. 
Sometimes,  where  there  exists  the  system  of  advances 
from  the  company's  coffers  on  the  men's  wages,  the  store 
profits  by  a  kind  of  moral  compulsion  to  spend  this  volun- 
tary advance  in  the  company  store,  although  more  tangible 
constraint  is  not  unknown:  "black  lists  are  often  kept  of 
slopers  [those  who  do  not  spend  the  advances  in  the  com- 
pany store]  ;  threats  of  dismissal  were  repeatedly  proved ; 
and  cases  of  actual  dismissal  .  .  .  are  not  rare."82  More- 
over, even  the  most  provident  among  the  employees  seem 
to  think  it  to  their  advantage  to  deal  at  least  to  some  extent 
at  the  company  store:  it  is  a  natural  impression  for  the 
worker  to  think  that  his  job  is  more  secure  if  he  caters  to 
his  employer.  The  dominance  which  the  employer  can 
secure  over  the  laborer  is  evident,  the  double  profits  which 
he  can  reap  are  enormous.  And,  moreover,  the  laborer 
rarely  gets  fair  play,  for  monopoly  and  the  credit  features 

of  a  company  store  allow  the  owner  to  advance  prices  to  a 



82  Report  of  the  Commissioners  Appointed  to  Inquire  into  the 
Truck  System,  1871,  p.  xvi. 


255]  THE  TERMS   OF   EMPLOYMENT  ICX) 

considerable  extent.  The  truck  system,  indeed,  seems  to 
call  most  urgently  for  state  regulation.88 

In  legislating  upon  this  subject  Maryland  has  had  a  check- 
ered experience.  The  coal  fields  in  the  two  western  coun- 
ties of  the  State  furnished  an  ideal  opportunity  for  the 
growth  of  the  company  store;  and,  though  the  conditions 
and  the  acts  passed  to  meet  those  conditions  are  not  of  prac- 
tical importance  to-day,  yet  because  of  the  number  of  these 
laws  and  because  of  the  decisions  based  upon  them  it  has 
been  thought  worth  while  to  spend  enough  time  on  them  at 
least  to  outline  them.  As  far  back  as  1868  the  legislature 
decreed  that  "  no  railroad  or  mining  corporation  .  .  .  shall 
own,  conduct  or  carry  on  any  store,  or  have  any  interest  in 
any  store."34  This  law  does  not  seem  to  have  been  very 
effective,  for  two  other  laws,  this  time  local  in  their  effect, 
were  later  enacted.  By  these  every  corporation  engaged  in 
mining  or  manufacturing  or  operating  a  railroad  in  Alle- 
ghany  and  Garrett  counties  was  compelled  to  pay  the  wages 
of  its  employees  in  legal  tender  of  the  United  States  ;35  and, 
in  Alleghany  County,  it  is  further  provided  that  "  no  such 
corporation  .  .  .  shall  issue  any  script  or  metallic  or  paper 
checks  in  payment  of  the  sums  due  such  employees,  nor 
shall  such  employees  make  any  contract  with  their  employ- 
ers by  which  such  employees  shall  be  compelled  to  purchase 
their  supplies,  merchandise  or  goods  from  any  private  or 
company  stores  owned  and  operated  by  said  employers ;  nor 
shall  .  .  .  [the  employers]  exercise  any  influence  whatever 
...  to  compel  their  employees  to  deal  with  any  particular 
merchant  or  storekeepers."38 

This  last  amendment  makes  this  law  about  as  inclusive 
and  adequate  as  it  is  possible  to  make  a  law  regulating  such 
a  multiform  evil.  It  is  the  direct  outgrowth  of  a  Maryland 

88  A  regulation  and  prohibition  of  the  truck  system  has  been  held 
constitutional  in  Knoxville  Iron  Co.  v.  Harbison,  183  U.  S.  13. 
"Laws  1868,  Ch.  471,  Sec.  217;  Code  1911,  Art.  23,  Sec.  311. 

85  Code  Public  Local  Laws  1888,  Art.  i,  Sec.  185;  Laws  1892, 
Ch.  445- 

86  Amendment  added  by  Laws  1900,  Ch.  453. 


HO  THE  LABOR   LAW   OF   MARYLAND  [256 

case37  construing  an  allied  act  and  of  a  Supreme  Court 
decision.38  To  understand  this  law  a  little  history  must  be 
indulged  in.  The  local  law  for  Alleghany  County  as  first 
passed  was  declared  constitutional  as  a  justified  exercise  of 
the  police  power  of  the  State  in  Shaffer  v.  Union  Mining 
Co.  ;39  but  it  was  held  in  this  case  that  an  assignment  of 
wages  to  merchants  who  were  tenants  of  the  mining  com- 
pany was  not  included  within  the  prohibition  of  the  act. 
This  decision  much  weakened  the  law,  for  the  truck  sys- 
tem has  been  found  just  as  noxious  when  the  store  is  run 
by  tenants  of  the  company  as  when  run  by  the  company 
itself.  The  law  in  fact  proved  inadequate  and  there  was 
passed  a  bill  rendering  it  unlawful  for  any  officer  or  direc- 
tor of  a  mining  or  railroad  corporation  to  have  any  interest 
in  any  general  store  in  Alleghany  County.40  This  act  was 
aimed  at  what  has  recently  become  well  known  as  interlock- 
ing directorates,  but  it  was  almost  immediately  declared 
unconstitutional  as  interfering  with  the  equal  protection  of 
the  laws.41  "Though  it  was  perfectly  competent,"  say  the 
court,  "  for  the  legislature  to  prevent  railroad  and  mining 
corporations  from  engaging  in  the  business  of  bartering  or 
selling  goods  .  .  .  ;  yet  it  was  not  within  the  power  of  the 
General  Assembly  to  deny  to  particular  individuals  who 
happened  to  be  officers  of  those  corporations,  and  merely 
because  they  were  such  officers  the  right  which  every  other 
citizen  of  the  country  .  .  .  possessed  to  sell  goods."  And 
further,  "  the  owners  of  a  mine  have  no  other  control  over 
the  employee  'than  that  which  may  result  from  employing 
him,  etc. ;  and  every  other  employer  of  labor  has  precisely 
the  same  control  over  those  who  obtain  or  wish  to  obtain 
employment  with  him.'"42  In  this  case  the  court  clearly 
refused  to  take  judicial  cognizance  of  the  truck  system  and 

87  Luman  v.  Kitchens,  90  Md.  14 ;  46  L.  R.  A.  393. 

88  Knoxville  Iron  Co.  v.  Harbison ;  see  above. 
SB  55  Md.  74- 

*°  Laws  1898,  Ch.  493. 

41  Luman  v.  Kitchens ;  see  above. 

42  Quoting  from  Frorer  v.  People,  141  111.  171 ;  16  L.  R.  A.  492. 


257]  THE  TERMS   OF   EMPLOYMENT  III 

especially  of  the  truck  system  as  it  flourished  in  Alleghany 
County,  Maryland.  The  case  was  decided  on  purely  legal 
grounds;  and,  being  one  of  those  cases  in  which  constitu- 
tionality was  peculiarly  a  question  of  fact,  it  is  submitted 
that  the  court  was  in  error.  This  case,  however,  is  not  so 
reactionary  and  destructive  as  a  case  which  followed  it,  that 
of  Luman  v.  Kitchens.  This  case  led  to  the  amendment  of 
the  earlier  law  and  the  amendment,  as  has  been  intimated, 
is  really  more  efficient  than  the  unconstitutional  act. 

Thus  far  only  those  laws  directly  attacking  the  truck 
system  have  been  considered;  but  since  the  truck  system 
depends  for  its  maintenance  upon  long  intervals  between 
pay  days,  acts  regulating  the  time  of  pay  will  be  practically 
as  efficacious  as  the  out-and-out  company  store  laws. 
Maryland  has  three  such  acts  on  her  statute  book,  though 
it  is  probable  that  only  one  is  really  constitutional.  This  is 
a  law  contained  in  the  corporation  article  of  the  code  de- 
creeing that  "  every  association  or  corporation  doing  busi- 
ness in  the  State  of  Maryland  employing  wage  earners  .  .  . 
in  the  business  of  mining,  manufacturing,  operating  a  steam 
or  electric  railroad,  street  railway,  telegraph,  telephone  or 
express  company  shall  make  payments  in  lawful  money  of 
the  United  States  semi-monthly  to  said  employees."43  This 
law  seems  to  include  all  businesses  mentioned  in  the  previ- 
ous law  pertaining  to  corporations  engaged  in  mining  and 
shipping  coal  in  Alleghany  County,*4  so  that  this  earlier  law 
is  entirely  superseded.  A  later  act  was  passed,  however, 
applying  the  same  terms  to  "  all  corporations  and  individual 
mine-owners  .  .  .  engaged  in  mining  coal  or  fire  clay  in 
Garrett  County."45  This  addition  of  "individual  mine- 
owners"  was  the  result  of  the  decision  of  Luman  v. 
Kitchens,48  which  was  interpreted  as  based  on  the  singling 
out  of  corporations  for  stricter  regulations.  In  State  v. 
Potomac  Coal  Company,47  however,  the  court  on  the  ground 

43  Code  1911,  Art.  23,  Sec.  123. 

44  Laws  1896,  Ch.  133. 

45  Laws  1910,  Ch.  2ii. 
48  Cited  above. 

47 116  Md.  380. 


112  THE  LABOR   LAW   OF   MARYLAND 

of  the  earlier  case  declared  the  later  act  unconstitutional  as 
a  violation  of  the  "  equal  protection  of  the  laws "  clause 
because  the  law  was  confined  to  the  mining  industry  in  the 
one  county.  The  court  again  based  its  decision  on  purely 
legal  grounds  and  seems  to  have  narrowed  the  police  power 
to  an  unreasonable  extent.  Though  the  court's  argument 
seems  discouragingly  restrictive,  and  not  specifically  based 
on  facts,  the  facts  do  nevertheless  to  a  great  degree  uphold 
it,  for  the  truck  system  in  1911  was  not  nearly  so  insidious 
as  it  was  when  the  court  refused  to  recognize  it  in  1899.  It 
is,  however,  lucky  that  the  adverse  decision  of  the  court 
came  after  the  truck  system  had  virtually  disappeared,  for 
it  would  have  been  practically  impossible  to  legislate  against 
it  if  the  industries  in  which  it  was  prevalent  could  not  have 
been  reached  by  special  legislation. 

Any  discussion  of  state  regulation  of  the  terms  of  em- 
ployment should  include  at  least  a  mention  of  the  tendency 
towards  state  aided  pensions  for  sickness,  old  age,  unem- 
ployment and  the  like.  This  movement  has  attained  great 
prominence  in  many  foreign  countries,  and  recently  Great 
Britain  has  followed  the  lead  of  the  more  radical  Domin- 
ions. One  such  scheme  of  state  aid  in  the  unemployment 
insurance  of  labor  unions  will  be  discussed  in  the  last  chap- 
ter as  a  means  whereby  the  state  might  obtain  control  of 
union  affairs.  As  such,  as  a  governmental  device,  these 
pensions  are  perhaps  justified;  but,  as  purely  social  legisla- 
tion, they  are  quite  beyond  the  police  power  of  the  state 
as  it  is  conceived  in  this  study,  whether  we  define  the  police 
power  from  a  legal  or  a  legislative  point  of  view. 


CHAPTER  VI 
SOME  MISCELLANEOUS  LAWS 

There  will  be  considered  in  this  chapter  a  number  of  laws 
which  are  only  incidentally  labor  laws,  but  which  play  an 
important  part  in  the  legal  and  social  welfare  of  Maryland. 
These  will  be  treated  under  four  heads :  ( i )  license  laws ; 
(2)  laws  governing  attachments  and  liens  for  wages — laws 
of  legal  practice  and  procedure  primarily;  (3)  child  wel- 
fare laws ;  and  (4)  State  employment  laws. 

Licenses. — There  is  in  Maryland  the  beginning  of  a  li- 
cense system.  In  so  far  as  it  is  intended  for  a  comprehen- 
sive system  of  licensing  occupations  in  order  to  make  the 
State  a  sponsor  for  the  proficiency  of  its  working  people, 
the  Maryland  license  laws  are  really  only  a  beginning,  but 
compared  with  the  license  laws  of  other  States,  they  seem 
fairly  extensive.  Licenses  are  required  of  barbers,  plumb- 
ers and  chauffeurs  throughout  the  State,  and  of  electricians, 
horseshoers,  moving  picture  operators,  stationary  engineers 
and  master  stevedores  in  Baltimore  City.  Practically  the 
only  important  occupation  licensed  in  other  States  which  is 
not  licensed  in  Maryland  is  mining;  but  withal  the  Mary- 
land miners  are  an  efficient  and  intelligent  class. 

Licenses  are  required  by  the  State  for  two  reasons. 
Some  license  laws,  as,  for  instance,  those  controlling  ped- 
dlers and  real  estate  dealers,  are  enacted  purely  for  revenue 
purposes.  They  indirectly  serve  as  police  measures,  but 
their  primary  purpose  is  to  secure  revenue.1  The  other 
class  of  license  laws,  beginning  with  those  regulating  the 
practice  of  medicine  and  law  and  extending  down  to  horse- 
shoers, are  enacted  primarily  as  police  measures  to  protect 
the  public  from  quacks  and  inefficient  workmen.  To  this 

1  See  Coates  v.  Locust  Point  Co.,  102  Md.  297. 
8  113 


114  THE  LABOR  LAW   OF   MARYLAND  [260 

class  belong  all  the  laws  affecting  the  laborer  except  per- 
haps the  master  stevedore  law,2  which  as  it  now  stands  in 
its  emasculated  form  is  hard  to  understand.  As  first  en- 
acted, it  required  both  a  license  fee  and  a  bond  to  secure 
the  payment  of  wages  to  the  journeymen  stevedores.  The 
Court  of  Appeals,  however,  declared  the  bonding  provision 
unconstitutional,  but  did  not  question  the  licensing  section  ;3 
yet  it  is  hard  to  see  why,  if  the  State  can  protect  those  work- 
ers who  are  hired  by  a  master  stevedore  against  fraud  and 
insolvency  by  a  twenty-five  dollar  license  fee,  it  cannot  more 
adequately  protect  them  by  a  thousand  dollar  bond.  The 
regard  of  the  courts  for  the  historical  activities  of  the  State 
and  their  aversion  towards  new  modes  of  State  activity  is 
perhaps  the  only  explanation. 

The  other  laws,4  if  considered  together,  suggest  an  inter- 
esting hypothesis.  Except  for  the  chauffeurs,  an  exception 
which  is  easily  explained,  all  the  occupations  licensed  in 
Maryland  are  organized  into  substantial  unions.  Is  the 
State,  perhaps  unconsciously,  rendering  a  most  valuable  aid 
to  the  organizing  of  these  occupations?  That  the  unions 
are  strongly  in  favor  of  these  laws  and  that  they  put  forth 
every  effort  of  which  they  are  capable  to  secure  them  is  an 
unconcealed  fact;  that  their  efforts  are  of  much  avail  and 
that  the  results  are  beneficial  is  more  debatable.  That  these 
laws  are  of  some  use  seems  indisputable.  A  typical  instance 
is  furnished  by  the  operation  of  the  laws  of  the  Middle 
Western  States  licensing  miners.  When  a  strike  is  the  or- 
der of  the  day,  the  men  in  the  mines  stop  work  and  the  mine 
owners  are  unable  to  fill  their  places  because  of  the  lack  of 
licensed  men  outside  the  ranks  of  the  strikers.  This  is  true, 

2  Baltimore  City  Charter  1915,  Sec.  7<x>A. 

8  Steeken  y.  State,  88  Md.  708. 

4 The  various  laws  are  codified  as  follows:  Barbers,  Code  1911, 
Art.  43,  Sees.  209-222;  Chauffers,  Code  1911,  Art.  56,  Sec.  139;  Elec- 
tricians, Baltimore  City  Charter  1915,  Sec.  663,  m-q;  Horse-shoers, 
Baltimore  City  Charter  1915,  Sec.  515,  a-f ;  Moving  Picture  Opera- 
tors, Laws  1912,  Ch.  814;  Plumbers,  Code  1911,  Art.  43,  Sees.  223- 
229,  with  exceptions  contained  in  Laws  1912,  Chs.  764,  845 ;  Station- 
ary Engineers,  Baltimore  City  Code  1906,  Sec.  427,  as  amended  by 
Laws  1910,  Ch.  662,  and  Sec.  428. 


26l]  SOME   MISCELLANEOUS   LAWS 

of  course,  only  if  employment  at  the  time  of  the  strike  is  at 
a  high  ebb ;  but  employment  usually  is  at  a  high  ebb  when  a 
strike  is  essayed,  for  this  weapon  is  only  efficient  in  pros- 
perous times.  The  a  priori  argument  advanced  as  to  the 
benefit  to  the  unions  of  licensing  laws  seems  again  to  be 
borne  out  by  the  fact  that  most  licensed  occupations  are 
organized,  though,  here  too,  the  argument  is  not  conclusive 
because  of  the  probable  functional  relation  of  organization 
and  license  laws.  The  argument  based  on  the  unorganized 
condition  of  such  licensed  occupations  as  trained  nurses  and 
chauffeurs,  which  is  often  used  to  offset  that  conclusion  that 
licensing  and  unionization  are  closely  related,  seems  hardly 
tenable  because  of  the  inherent  nature  of  these  occupations. 
That  licensing  is  not  a  sufficiently  strong  unionizing  device 
to  unionize  unorganizable  occupations  is  freely  conceded, 
but  it  is  nevertheless  strongly  maintained  .that  it  is  a  stimu- 
lus towards  organization.  The  desirability  of  unionization 
by  means  of  a  licensing  system  is  doubtful.  It  certainly 
tends  to  make  the  union  policy  one  of  restriction  rather 
than  of  progress ;  and  if  its  effect  is  to  cause  the  American 
unions  to  pattern  their  policy  after  that  of  the  British 
unions,  it  is  open  to  strong  disapprobation. 

The  administration  of  these  laws  is  not  of  much  impor- 
tance in  this  study  and  as  it  is  practically  the  same  in  all 
the  laws,  one  explanation  will  suffice.  Except  for  the  chauf- 
feurs, where  the  administration  is  quite  naturally  in  the 
hands  of  the  automobile  commissioner,  all  of  the  laws  are 
enforced  by  a  board  generally  of  men  practiced  in  the  regu- 
lated occupation  and  generally  appointed  by  the  governor. 
The  meetings  of  this  board  are  in  most  cases  left  to  the  dis- 
cretion of  the  board  itself,  though  sometimes  a  minimum  is 
fixed  and  sometimes,  even  in  general  laws,  a  certain  number 
of  meetings  must  be  held  in  Baltimore.  The  members  of 
the  board  are  usually  paid  a  per  diem  and  travelling  ex- 
penses to  be  obtained  from  the  fees  of  the  applicants  for 
licenses.  The  board  is  allowed  full  discretion  in  setting  the 
examination  where  an  examination  is  required,  and  this  dis- 


Il6  THE   LABOR  LAW   OF   MARYLAND  [262 

cretion  seems  well  placed  because  of  the  practical  training 
of  the  members  of  the  board.  The  applicant  must  qualify 
only  once  before  the  granting  body,  but  in  the  case  of 
plumbers,  moving  picture  operators  and  stationary  engi- 
neers the  license  is  good  for  only  one  year  and  the  worker 
is  of  right  entitled  to  a  renewal  upon  the  payment  of  a  re- 
newal fee.  There  has  been  some  litigation  as  to  the  inter- 
pretation and  application  of  these  laws,5  but  since  these  laws 
are  not  of  great  importance  in  the  sum  total  of  labor  legis- 
lation of  the  State,  the  litigation  needs  no  discussion. 

Attachments  and  Liens. — There  must  next  be  considered 
certain  laws  which,  if  not  in  all  cases  a  protection  of  the 
laborer,  aim  to  further  his  welfare  in  legal  proceedings. 
Maryland  does  not  hold  any  peculiar  position  in  regard  to 
these  laws,  neither  above  nor  below  the  average,  for  it  has 
been  generally  agreed  that  they  are  just  and  necessary  and, 
in  most  States,  are  of  the  same  general  nature.  They  in- 
clude mechanics'  lien  laws,  laws  preferring  wages  in  assign- 
ments and  similar  laws.  These  laws  are  justified  upon  the 
ground  that  the  workingman,  since  he  must  always  work  a 
certain  length  of  time  before  he  receives  his  wages,  is  al- 
ways to  a  degree  involuntarily  in  the  debt  of  his  employer. 
The  employer  really  stands  more  in  the  nature  of  a  trustee 
to  the  workingman  than  of  a  debtor,  for  the  laborer  hardly 
looks  upon  his  contract  as  one  in  which  he  extends  credit 
to  the  employer.  It  is  right,  therefore,  that  the  laborer 
should  have  greater  security  for  his  wages  than  the  ordi- 
nary debtor  for  his  debt.  The  truck  laws,  which  have  al- 
ready been  considered,  are  a  related  branch  of  legislation, 
which  seems  proper  irrespective  of  the  conditions  of  the 
laborers  as  a  class. 

In  pursuance  of  this  policy,  the  Maryland  legislature 
early  began  to  accumulate  these  laws  on  the  statute  books. 
Thus  there  are  mechanics'  liens  extending  to  buildings,  ma- 

5  Concerning  the  plumber  law,  see  Davidson  v.  State,  77  Md.  388. 
For  the  interpretation  of  the  barber  law,  see  State  v.  Tag,  100 
Md.  588. 


263]  SOME   MISCELLANEOUS  LAWS  1 1/ 

chines,  wharves,  bridges,  boats6  and  even  wells  in  Garrett 
County,7  giving  to  those  engaged  in  the  construction  of  these 
structures  priority  in  the  security  for  their  wages  over  all 
except  in  the  case  of  vessels,  prior  mortgages  and  sales.  So 
also,  in  insolvency  assignments,  wages  due  for  not  more 
than  three  months  are  preferred  to  all  claims  except  prior 
recorded  liens  on  the  property  ;8  and  in  an  execution  against 
property  in  Alleghany  and  Garrett  counties  sufficient  of  this 
property  is  exempted  to  pay  all  wage  claims.9  In  a  differ- 
ent spirit  but  again  from  public  policy  toward  all  and  not 
toward  a  class  is  the  exemption  of  all  tools  and  mechanical 
instruments  from  execution  on  a  judgment.10  Still  differ- 
ent and  really  quite  without  the  scope  of  labor  legislation 
are  those  laws  regulating  strictly  the  attachment11  and  as- 
signment12 of  wages.  These  last  are  merely  mentioned 
because  the  words  "wages"  or  "laborer"  occurs  in  them 
and,  therefore,  necessarily  the  workingman  is  affected  by 
them ;  they  are  not  social  legislation  to  so  great  an  extent 
as  are  those,  for  example,  preferring  the  laborer  in  insol- 
vency. 

Child  Welfare. — A  third  group  of  laws  deal  with  chil- 
dren, apprenticeship  and  education.  Their  philosophy  is 
the  same  as  that  of  the  laws  considered  in  the  preceding 
chapter,  which  the  State  has  enacted  in  conservation  of  child 
life.  Their  subject  matter,  however,  is  not  the  relation  of 
employer  and  employee,  but  the  policy  of  the  State  toward 
its  children  and,  hence,  is  not  included  in  the  terms  of 
employment. 

Historically,  the  apprentice  law  came  first.  When  it  is 
remembered  that  the  first  Maryland  enactment  of  this  kind 
was  as  early  as  171 5,13  it  is  hardly  necessary  to  explain 

•  Code  1911,  Art.  63,  Sees.  1-52. 

7  Laws  1894,  Ch.  608. 

8  Code  1911,  Art.  47,  Sec.  15. 

9  Code  Public  Local  Laws  1888,  Art.  i,  Sec.  193 ;  Art.  12,  Sec.  149. 
™  Code  1911,  Art.  83,  Sec.  10. 

11  Code  1911,  Art.  9,  Sees.  33-34. 

12  Code  1911,  Art.  8,  Sees.  11-17. 
18  See  Laws  1715,  Ch.  19. 


Il8  THE   LABOR   LAW   OF   MARYLAND  [264 

that  the  State  has  not  seen  fit  to  regulate  the  terms  of  ap- 
prenticeship, which  it  has  properly  left  to  the  individual  and 
especially  the  union,  but  has  merely  laid  down  the  funda- 
mental principles  upon  which  the  contract  or  status  of  ap- 
prenticeship is  based.  The  law  as  it  now  stands,14  for  in- 
stance, allows  the  father,  but  not  the  mother,15  to  bind  out 
a  minor  child  until  the  age  of  twenty-one  in  the  case  of 
males  and  eighteen  in  that  of  females.  The  Orphans*  Court 
may  also  bind  out  for  the  same  term  any  orphan  whose  in- 
heritance is  not  sufficient  to  support  him,  or  any  other  child 
whose  parents  fail  or  are  unable  to  support  him.  Of  course 
the  prohibitions  against  child  labor  are  binding  upon  the 
Orphans'  Court. 

Then  there  is  the  elaborate  school  attendance  law16  of 
1912  which  was  passed  in  connection  with  the  child  labor 
law  of  that  year  and  which  requires  every  child  not  men- 
tally deficient  between  the  ages  of  eight  and  fourteen  to 
attend  school  throughout  the  entire  session,  and  also  every 
child  between  the  ages  of  fourteen  and  sixteen  unless  he 
has  been  granted  an  employment  certificate.  An  efficient 
and  complete  administration  has  been  provided  in  this  act 
and  in  these  respects  it  is  perfectly  adequate.  The  useful- 
ness of  the  act,  however,  depends  upon  the  general  useful- 
ness of  the  school  system,  and  although  the  Maryland  school 
system  is  perhaps  above  the  average,  it  still  falls  short  of 
the  highest  standards.  Without  going  beyond  the  scope  of 
this  study  mention  may  be  made  of  the  schools  of  mining 
which  have  been  authorized  in  Alleghany  County  for  the 
large  mining  population  of  that  county.17 

The  latest  activity  of  the  State  in  the  field  of  child  wel- 
fare is  the  limited  mothers'  pension  law  of  I9i6.18  Here 
again  we  have  a  stretching  of  the  function  of  the  State 
until  it  verges  rather  dangerously  upon  socialism.  The  law, 

"Code  1911,  Art.  6. 

15  Baker  v.  Lauterback,  68  Md.  69. 

16  Laws  1912,  Ch.  173. 

«  Code  Public  Local  Laws  1888,  Art.  i,  Sees.  218-225. 
18  Laws  1916,  Ch.  670. 


265]  SOME   MISCELLANEOUS  LAWS 

however,  though  properly  classed  as  social  legislation,  is 
hardly  in  the  rubric  of  labor  legislation,  and  an  intensive 
examination  of  its  philosophy  would  be  superfluous.  "  Any 
mother  of  a  child  or  children  under  the  age  of  fourteen 
years,  whose  husband  is  dead,  and  who  is  unable  to  support 
it  or  them  and  maintain  her  home"  may  apply  for  relief 
to  the  county  commissioners  in  the  counties  or  to  the  special 
Board  for  Mothers'  Relief  for  Baltimore  City.  If,  after  in- 
vestigation, it  is  found  "that  unless  relief  is  granted,  the 
mother  will  be  unable  to  support  and  educate  her  children, 
and  that  they  may  become  a  public  charge,"  she  is  referred 
to  the  Juvenile  Court  which  may  order  to  be  paid  her  twelve 
dollars  per  month  for  the  oldest  child,  ten  dollars  for  the 
next,  and  six  dollars  for  each  additional  child  up  to  forty 
dollars  a  month.  The  administrative  agency  is  to  keep  in 
touch  with  its  dependents,  to  visit  them  at  least  once  every 
two  months,  and  to  see  that  the  relief  is  properly  applied 
for  the  welfare  of  the  children. 

State  Employment. — The  last  series  of  laws  which  fall 
into  a  clearly  defined  group  are  those  laws  in  which  the 
State  regulates  the  terms  of  employment  of  its  own  em- 
ployees or  those  of  its  subdivisions.  In  the  United  States 
this  kind  of  legislation  is  generally  political  in  its  nature, 
it  is  generally  passed  primarily  as  a  bid  for  the  labor  vote 
and  only  secondarily  as  a  social  measure ;  but  on  the  Conti- 
nent, in  Germany  particularly,  this  species  of  legislation 
plays  an  important  part  in  the  administrative  organization 
of  the  country. 

In  the  first  place,  it  has  been  decreed  that  preference 
shall  be  given  to  voters  in  filling  the  jobs  on  the  public  work 
of  Baltimore  City.19  A  probable  reason  for  this  law  is  to 
enable  the  party  in  control  of  the  city  government  to  use 
the  city's  money  for  electioneering  purposes.  The  other 
laws  regulating  this  subject  are  not  so  brazen,  yet  their 
political  effect  is  as  certain.  "For  all  laborers,  workmen 
or  mechanics  who  may  be  employed  by  or  on  behalf  of  the 

19  Baltimore  City  Code  1906,  Art.  35,  Sec.  6. 


I2O  THE  LABOR  LAW  OF   MARYLAND  [266 

Mayor  and  City  Council  of  Baltimore,"  eight  hours  shall 
constitute  a  day's  work  except  in  emergencies.  Moreover, 
"  the  rate  of  per  diem  wages  paid  to  laborers,  workmen  or 
mechanics  employed  directly  by  the  Mayor,  etc.,  shall  not 
be  less  than  two  dollars  per  diem,"  and  where  the  work  is 
contracted  out  "not  less  than  the  current  rate  of  per  diem 
wages  in  the  locality  where  the  work  is  performed  shall  be 
paid  "  ;20  and  these  wages  shall  be  paid  weekly.21  This  leg- 
islation has  always  been  upheld  as  constitutional,  but  it 
hardly  seems  that  the  State  is  performing  a  proper  legisla- 
tive function  in  enacting  these  laws.  It  is  quite  true 
that  the  State  has  a  right  to  stipulate  in  its  contracts  any 
terms  that  it  wishes,  but  efficiency  demands  that  an  admin- 
istrative head  have  some  discretion  in  respect  to  the  terms 
of  employment  which  he  contracts  for.  The  laborer  would 
hardly  suffer  from  the  exercise  of  administrative  discre- 
tion and  its  resulting  elasticity.  Yet  it  must  be  admitted 
that  practically  every  State  of  the  Union  has  felt  the  neces- 
sity of  enacting  legislation  of  this  type. 

Massachusetts  State  employment  legislation  represents  a 
more  extreme  type.  Superficially  it  may  seem  a  startling 
step  towards  socialism,  but  on  closer  examination  it  seems 
to  have  been  an  attempt  to  secure  efficient  administration. 
It  is  aimed  at  attaining  that  thing,  so  harsh-sounding  to  the 
democratic  ear,  yet  seeming  so  necessary  in  a  representative 
government,  a  bureaucracy.  In  the  first  place,  a  civil  service 
examination  must  be  passed  before  one  is  eligible  for  a  state 
job.22  Then  to  secure  some  sort  of  permanency  in  state 
employment  and  to  make  this  employment  more  attractive, 
a  state-aided  old-age  pension  scheme  is  devised  for  state, 
county  and  city  employees.23  It  is  a  well-known  fact  that 
Massachusetts  has  a  very  efficient  government.  How  far 
its  efficiency  is  due  to  the  measures  just  mentioned  is  diffi- 

80  Laws  1910,  Ch.  94,  Sec.  2. 
21  Baltimore  City  Code  1906,  Sec.  47. 
z  Massachusetts  Revised  Laws  1902,  Ch.  19,  Sees.  12-13. 
23  Mass.  Laws  1910,  Ch.  559;  Laws  1911,  Ch.  532. 


267]  SOME   MISCELLANEOUS   LAWS  121 

cult  to  estimate;  but  in  view  of  European  experience  it 
seems  that  something  like  the  Massachusetts  plan  is  neces- 
sary to  invigorate  American  administration. 

Laws  which  defy  classification  are :  the  Sunday  rest  law,24 
the  law  establishing  Labor  Day,25  a  law  requiring  every 
employer  to  allow  all  of  his  employees  sufficient  time  for 
voting  at  all  elections,26  and  a  law  of  1912  requiring  physi- 
cians to  report  all  cases  of  occupational  sickness  which  they 
are  called  upon  to  attend.27  The  last  named  law  as  it  now 
stands  is  designed  merely  for  statistical  purposes ;  but  since 
it  may  lead  to  greater  things  in  the  way  of  the  prevention 
of  occupational  diseases  it  is  properly  treated  as  a  labor  en- 
actment. Finally,  in  pursuance  of  the  special  care  which 
the  law  has  always  had  for  seamen,  there  is  on  the  Mary- 
land books  a  law  protecting  them  from  the  solicitations  of 
any  kind  of  sailors'  employment  agencies.28 


24  Code  1914,  Art.  27,  Sec.  435. 

25  Baltimore  City  Code  1906,  Art.  15,  Sec.  2. 

26  Code  1911,  Art.  33,  Sec.  91. 

27  Laws  1912,  Ch.  165,  Sec.  sA. 

28  Code  1911,  Art.  84,  Sees.  1-7. 


CHAPTER  VII 
THE  ADMINISTRATIVE  SYSTEM 

The  lawyer  usually  feels  that  administration  and  law  are 
things  apart  and  a  legal  treatise  generally  contents  itself 
with  a  consideration  of  the  substantive  law,  leaving  admin- 
istration to  the  care  of  the  social  reformer.  With  the  ex- 
ception of  the  law  of  the  labor  union,  however,  the  present 
study  has  been  confined  to  the  analysis  of  the  works  of 
social  reformers.  Moreover,  we  have  been  dealing  with  the 
science  of  legislation  quite  as  much  as  with  the  science  of 
law,  and  legislation  generally  includes  administration.  The 
common  law  and  most  codifying  legislation  is  remedial, 
compensatory;  labor  legislation  is  restrictive,  prohibitive. 
Labor  legislation,  though  it  is  often  attacked  as  class  legis- 
lation in  its  narrow  and  obnoxious  sense,  is  in  reality  en- 
acted for  the  benefit  of  the  community  as  a  whole ;  its  vio- 
lation is  more  in  the  nature  of  a  crime  against  the  state 
than  an  injury  to  the  individual.  In  the  community,  there- 
fore, lies  the  responsibility  of  guarding  against  the  viola- 
tion of  this  legislation,  against  the  slightest  deviation  from 
its  prescriptions.  In  the  community,  not  in  the  individual, 
must  rest  the  initiative  of  bringing  this  law  into  operation. 

An  adequate  labor  law  is  accordingly  dependent  upon 
efficient  administrative  provisions.  As  a  chain  is  no  stronger 
than  its  weakest  link,  neither  is  labor  legislation  more  effi- 
cacious than  its  administrative  system.  Considering  Mary- 
land legislation  from  the  standpoint  of  administrative  effi- 
ciency one  cannot  grant  it  high  rank.  Even  the  greatest 
optimist  would  find  himself  somewhat  doubtful,  to  say  the 
least,  of  the  sagacity  of  the  sovereign  people  of  Maryland 
after  a  talk  with  those  charged  with  the  administration  of 
the  labor  law.  In  order  to  give  this  subject  adequate  treat- 

122 


269]  THE  ADMINISTRATIVE  SYSTEM  123 

ment  in  this  study,  it  has  seemed  best  to  give  first  a  com- 
plete description  of  the  administration  as  it  now  exists  and 
has  existed,  refraining  as  far  as  possible  from  any  critical 
comment.  Having  tried  to  understand  the  existing  system, 
we  shall  subject  it  to  criticism  and  then  attempt  to  outline 
an  adequate  scheme  of  administration. 

Before  going  any  further,  it  must  be  understood,  the 
title  of  this  chapter  to  the  contrary  notwithstanding,  that 
there  is  no  administrative  system  for  carrying  out  the  labor 
laws  of  Maryland.  Administration  there  is,  but  system — 
hardly.  This  criticism,  of  course,  has  been  partly  met  by  the 
legislation  of  1916;  but  this  reform — for  reform  it  was — 
hardly  necessitates  any  qualification  of  the  statement  that 
Maryland,  like  most  other  American  States,  is  happy-go- 
lucky  when  it  comes  to  legislating.  A  preconceived  system 
is  rarely,  if  ever,  thought  out.  An  evil  arises;  it  is  legis- 
lated against ;  and,  if  administration  must  be  provided  for, 
a  special  official  or  board  is  designated.  That  is  what  has 
happened  in  the  labor  legislation.  In  spite  of  the  recent 
centralizing  amendment,  there  are  still  eight  separate  and 
distinct  administrative  agencies  for  Maryland  labor  law, 
only  one  of  which,  the  State  Board  of  Labor  and  Statistics, 
is  charged  with  the  administration  of  more  than  one  law. 
Besides  this  board,  there  are  the  State  Board  of  Health, 
the  city  inspector  of  buildings,  the  city  health  commissioner, 
the  Industrial  Accident  Commission — all  real  administrative 
devices,  and  the  police  marshals,  the  constable  of  Carroll 
County,  and  the  city  collector  of  water  rents,  who  perform 
administrative  functions  in  connection  with  the  labor  law. 

State  Board  of  Labor  and  Statistics. — By  far  the  most 
important  administrative  agency  is  the  State  Board  of  Labor 
and  Statistics.  This,  by  the  act  of  I9I6,1  is  the  Maryland 
equivalent  of  a  labor  department,  though  still  a  rather  cir- 
cumscribed equivalent.  It  is  the  successor  to  and  an  im- 
provement upon  the  old  Bureau  of  Statistics  and  Informa- 

1  Laws  1916,  Ch.  406. 


124  THE  LABOR  LAW  OF   MARYLAND 

tion,  which,  as  originally  established  in  i884,2  was  hardly 
more  than  what  its  name  implies,  a  bureau  for  the  dissemi- 
nation of  information,  but  which  by  gradual  accretion  and 
the  accompanying  process  of  selection  was  burdened  more 
and  more  with  the  enforcement  of  the  labor  law,  until  within 
the  last  two  or  three  years  it  had  come  to  confine  itself  en- 
tirely to  labor  problems.  The  new  state  board  is,  of  course, 
entirely  devoted  to  labor  problems.  The  old  bureau  was 
the  only  centralizing  influence  in  the  Maryland  labor  law 
and  the  endeavor  of  the  legislation  of  1916  was.  to  increase 
this  centralization. 

The  State  Board  of  Labor  and  Statistics  is  composed  of 
three  commissioners  appointed  by  the  governor  for  a  two- 
year  term.  One  of  the  commissioners  is  designated  chair- 
man by  the  governor  at  a  salary  of  twenty-five  hundred  dol- 
lars and  the  other  two  are  merely  advisory  members  of  the 
board  The  chairman  is  the  executive  head  of  the  board 
and  most  of  the  activities  of  the  department  are  directed  by 
him  personally.  The  board  as  a  whole  meets  only  once 
a  month  to  determine  the  policy  of  the  department.  Its 
business,  however,  is,  it  would  seem,  more  to  ratify  the  acts 
of  the  chairman  than  to  lay  down  any  positive  policy,  for 
the  chairman  with  his  more  intimate  knowledge  of  the  af- 
fairs of  the  department  should  be  able  to  dictate  rather 
effectively  the  administrative  program  of  the  board.  This 
is  especially  so  for  the  reason  that  the  duties  of  the  board 
are  not  administrative  in  the  broader  sense,  as  described  in 
the  fourth  chapter,  but  are  almost  entirely  executive.  The 
Maryland  legislature  followed  the  plans  of  New  York  and 
Massachusetts,  but  did  not  give  the  commissioners  the  ad- 
ministrative powers  which  they  have  in  those  States.  The 
board  is  a  good  beginning,  but  as  the  law  now  stands,  the 
two  advisory  members  seem  somewhat  superfluous. 

"The  State  Board  of  Labor  and  Statistics  is  authorized 
and  empowered  to  appoint  .  .  .  such  deputies,  inspectors, 
assistants,  and  employees  of  every  kind  as  may  be  necessary 

2  Laws  1884,  Ch.  211 ;  Code  1911,  Art.  89,  Sec.  i. 


THE  ADMINISTRATIVE  SYSTEM  125 

for  the  performance  of  the  duties  now  or  hereafter  imposed 
upon  it,"  provided,  however,  that  all  appointments  shall  be 
subject  to  the  approval  of  the  governor.3  The  board  has 
now4  sixteen  employees,  including  two  medical  examiners, 
two  boiler  inspectors,  two  mining  inspectors,  its  regular  in- 
spectors, officers  to  issue  child  labor  permits,  clerks  and 
stenographers.  These  positions  are  all  frankly  regarded 
as  political  plums.  The  only  qualification  needed  by  an  ap- 
plicant is  sufficient  political  "  pull "  in  his  or  her  ward.  Not 
only  that,  but  since  the  board  cannot  hire  the  cheapest  ser- 
vice without  the  approval  of  the  governor,  it  results  that 
when  once  employed,  it  is  impossible  to  discharge  for  any 
reason  an  inspector  upon  whom  the  party  in  power  depends 
to  carry  his  ward.  This  is  absolutely  true  of  the  men  em- 
ployed in  the  department.  The  women,  it  is  said,  are  easier 
to  remove  on  account  of  inefficiency  because  they  do  not 
swing  so  many  votes.  Moreover,  I  have  been  told,  though 
my  informant  is  a  woman,  the  then  assistant-chief  of  the 
old  bureau,  that  as  a  whole  the  women  are  more  likely  to 
be  efficient  than  the  men ;  and  certainly  they  take  their  work 
more  seriously.  Yet  it  cannot  be  proposed  that  all  the  in- 
spectors should  be  women,  for  men  are  required  for  some 
jobs.  About  half  the  employees  of  the  board  are  women. 
The  duties  of  the  board  are  many  and  varied.  Inherited 
from  the  old  bureau  is  its  duty  to  collect  and  disseminate 
information.  The  board  is  "to  collect  statistics  and  ex- 
amine into  the  condition  of  labor  in  this  State,  with  especial 
reference  to  wages,  and  the  causes  of  strikes  and  disagree- 
ments between  employers  and  employees."5  In  the  law  are 
set  forth  many  other  matters  of  economic  interest  concern- 
ing which  the  board  is  ordered  to  investigate  and  publish 
information,  but  of  late  the  board  has  confined  itself  rather 
closely  to  labor  conditions.  In  pursuance  of  the  duty  im- 
posed upon  it  by  these  sections  of  the  law,  the  board  pub- 
lishes annually  a  lengthy  report  to  the  governor. 

8  Laws  1916,  Ch.  406,  Sec.  i,  Par.  3. 

4  July,  1916. 

0  Code  1911,  Art.  89,  Sec.  2;  Laws  1888,  Ch.  173. 


126  THE  LABOR  LAW  OF   MARYLAND  [2/2 

The  board  is  also  empowered  "  to  organize,  establish  and 
conduct  free  employment  agencies,  in  such  parts  of  the 
State  as  it  may  deem  advisable,  for  the  free  use  of  the  citi- 
zens of  the  State."6  This  is  a  great  improvement  over  the 
old  law,  which  provided  for  only  one  agency,  but  it  is  still 
deficient  in  that  the  legislature  does  not  seem  to  realize  the 
seriousness  of  the  problem  of  unemployment.  It  is  now 
usually  held  that  a  system  of  free  employment  offices  which 
aims  to  increase  the  fluidity  of  the  labor  market  is  one  of  the 
most  efficient  remedies  of  unemployment.7  As  a  conse- 
quence of  this,  the  State  should  expend  every  means  to  fur- 
nish the  most  adequate  system.  This  Maryland  has  hardly 
done.  The  board  has  established  agencies  in  Baltimore, 
Cumberland,  Hagerstown  and  on  the  Eastern  Shore,  but 
these  agencies  are  not  closely  enough  coordinated.  In  con- 
nection with  the  establishment  of  free  employment  agen- 
cies, the  board  should  have  the  licensing  and  supervision 
of  private  employment  agencies ;  but  this  power  is  vested  in 
the  city  collector  of  water  rents.8 

The  state  board,  it  will  be  remembered,  has  also  in  its 
charge  the  administration  of  the  law  providing  for  the  set- 
tlement of  labor  disputes.9 

The  chief  duty  of  the  board,  however,  is  the  inspection 
of  factories  and  workshops.  There  are  three  inspection 
laws  which  the  board  enforces,  the  factory  inspection  and 
industrial  registration  law,  the  child  labor  law,  and  the 
women's  ten-hour  law.  For  this  inspection  the  board  has 
appointed  five  inspectors  in  Baltimore  City,  one,  with  the 
possibility  of  an  increase  to  two  in  Western  Maryland,  and 
one  on  the  Eastern  Shore,  each  at  a  salary  of  about  one 
thousand  dollars.  For  the  purposes  of  this  inspection,  Bal- 

6  Code  1911,  Art.  89,  Sec.  2,  Par.  7,  as  amended  by  Laws  1916,  Ch. 
406,  Sec.  2. 

7  For  a  full  treatment  of  this  subject,  see  an  article  on  state  em- 
ployment agencies  by  Wm.  M.  Leiserson  in  29  Political  Science 
Quarterly,  p.  28. 

8  Ordinances  of  Mayor  and  City  Council  of  Baltimore,  1909-10, 
No.  433. 

9  See  Chapter  II. 


2/3]  THE   ADMINISTRATIVE   SYSTEM 

timore  is  divided  into  five  districts,  each  of  which  is  as- 
signed to  an  inspector  who  is  responsible  for  the  inspection 
and  conditions  in  his  district.  How  this  responsibility  is 
enforced  has  not  yet  been  worked  out  and  seems  to  be  in 
a  rather  vague  state,  but  a  system  of  checking  up  could  be 
easily  instituted.  But  this  localization  of  the  work  of  an 
inspector  can  lead  to  valuable  results  if  the  inspector  by 
frequent  visits  can  get  into  friendly  relations  with  the  em- 
ployer and  persuade  rather  than  force  him  to  better  the 
conditions  of  his  plant.  It  is  doubtful  whether  this  con- 
summation can  be  attained  under  the  present  law,  but  the 
beginning  is  worth  while.  In  the  first  place,  the  laws  as 
they  now  exist  lay  down  exact  rules  and  leave  nothing  to 
the  discretion  of  the  board  or  inspector,  and  the  instruc- 
tions given  to  the  inspectors  accentuate  the  routine  charac- 
ter of  their  work.  In  the  second  place,  the  inspector  has 
to  inspect  in  pursuance  of  three  separate  acts  and  it  seems 
that  the  districts  will  be  too  large  for  the  intensive  inspec- 
tion that  this  plan  requires.  It  is  doubtful  in  fact  whether 
five  inspectors  are  sufficient  for  the  minimum  efficiency  of 
the  laws.  Finally,  the  character  of  the  inspectors  who  are 
political  appointees  of  doubtful  efficiency  is  such  as  to  make 
decidedly  improbable  the  attainment  of  the  best  results  and 
to  render  doubtful  the  careful  inspection  which  the  laws 
require. 

Turning  now  to  the  first  of  these  laws  which  the  board 
enforces,  the  factory  inspection  and  industrial  registration 
law,10  we  shall  examine  the  administration  of  it  in  detail 
before  considering  the  other  two  laws.  It  has  already  been 
said  that  the  inspection  facilities  for  the  enforcement  of  this 
law  are  deficient  both  in  quantity  and  quality;  but  even 
with  four  or  five  inspections  per  shop  a  year  by  trained  in- 
spectors, which  would  furnish  an  adequate  inspection,  it  is 
doubtful  whether  this  act  could  reach  the  pinnacle  of  effi- 
ciency. As  far  as  obtaining  information  and  statistics  from 
the  employers  and  workers  covered  by  this  act,  the  board 

10  Laws  1914,  Ch.  779. 


128  THE  LABOR  LAW  OF  MARYLAND  [2/4 

has  full  and  discretionary  authority,  and  the  reports  in  this 
respect  are  valuable,  notwithstanding  their  incompleteness 
due  to  the  shiftless  methods  of  the  inspectors.  When,  how- 
ever, the  actual  enforcement  of  the  sanitary  and  safety  pro- 
visions of  the  law  is  considered  it  is  obvious  that  the  di- 
vision of  authority  in  the  enforcement  of  this  act  makes 
completeness  impossible. 

When  the  inspectors  are  sent  out  on  their  tours  of  inves- 
tigation, their  duty  is  to  visit  and  inspect  thoroughly  every 
factory,  workshop  or  tenement  shop  in  the  territory  to  which 
they  have  been  assigned.  Upon  visiting  the  work  place  the 
inspector  notes  the  toilet  conditions,  the  presence  of  fire- 
escapes  and  the  location  of  staircases,  the  existence  of  any 
communicable  disease,  and,  if  the  shop  savors  to  the  least 
degree  of  tenement  or  loft  shop,  the  inspector  further  meas- 
ures the  cubic  capacity  of  the  room.  This  is  the  routine 
whether  the  inspection  be  within  the  regular  investigation 
or  whether  it  be  undertaken  upon  the  application  of  a  home- 
worker  for  a  license  for  his  shop.  The  standards  of  the 
inspection  are  the  same  in  both  cases,  for  the  license,  as 
will  be  remembered,  is  revocable  at  any  time  by  the  board. 
After  completing  the  investigating  for  the  day,  the  inspector 
returns  to  the  office  and  notes  the  results  of  his  inspection 
on  the  forms  provided  for  filing.  That  is  as  far  as  the  in- 
spector goes. 

The  report  as  thus  filed  is  subject  to  the  authority  of 
three  separate  administrative  agencies.  The  board  has  the 
power  in  itself  to  enforce  only  the  provision  limiting  the 
number  of  persons  employed  in  any  room  to  one  to  each 
five  hundred  cubic  feet  of  air  space.  If  the  shop  inspected 
seems  to  lack  adequate  fire-escapes  required  by  law,  the 
report  is  referred  to  the  city  inspector  of  buildings.  In  hrni 
is  vested  the  duty  of  visiting  and  inspecting  all  manufac- 
tories employing  twenty-five  or  more  persons  and  of  ruling 
on  the  adequacy  of  fire-escapes.11  Neither  of  these  duties 

11  Baltimore  City  Charter  1915,  Sees.  80-81 ;  Ordinances  of  Balti- 
more, 1908-09,  No.  155,  Sec.  3,  Pars.  6-7 ;  Laws  1908,  Ch.  495. 


2/5]  THE   ADMINISTRATIVE   SYSTEM  129 

is  very  strictly  enforced.  The  inspection  he  leaves  entirely 
in  the  hands  of  the  State  Board  of  Labor  and  Statistics,  and 
perhaps  it  is  better  so,  although  the  city  department  has,  in 
fact,  a  number  of  inspectors.  The  provisions  for  fire- 
escapes  are  interpreted  so  loosely  that,  as  has  been  said, 
they  are  considered  fulfilled  if  the  house  in  which  the  shop 
is  located  has  two  staircases  of  any  kind  in  different  parts 
of  the  building  or  one  central  staircase.  The  result  of  this 
division  of  authority,  as  is  always  the  case,  is  that  the  law 
is  practically  nullified.  The  state  board  is  afraid,  and  in 
truth  is  hardly  empowered,  to  make  more  stringent  regula- 
tions than  those  of  the  city  building  inspector,  so  that  here 
there  is  no  compelling  authority.  The  building  inspector, 
on  the  other  hand,  does  not  consider  himself  delegated  with 
any  authority  to  protect  the  safety  of  the  employees.  As 
the  secretary  of  the  department  once  said:  "Oh,  no;  we 
don't  make  any  trouble.  We  are  a  kind  of  complaint  de- 
partment. The  fire  department  and  the  labor  department 
send  us  their  complaints  and  we  try  to  straighten  them 
out."  The  "straightening"  is  hardly  in  the  direction  of 
strictness. 

As  for  the  sanitary  conditions  of  the  shop,  or  tenement, 
a  different  course  of  proceeding  is  established.  In  the  first 
place,  it  is  provided  by  statute  that  before  any  license  for  a 
tenement  is  issued  the  records  of  the  local  health  depart- 
ment shall  be  investigated,  and  if  they  show  "  the  presence 
of  any  infectious,  contagious  or  communicable  disease,  or 
the  existence  of  any  unsanitary  conditions,"  the  license  may 
be  refused  without  any  inspection  of  the  room  or  apart- 
ment. Usually,  however,  the  room  or  shop  is  investigated, 
and  then  the  report  referred  to  the  local  health  department. 
If  the  health  department  finds  from  its  own  records  and  the 
report  of  the  inspector  that  the  place  is  sanitary,  a  license  is 
always  issued  by  the  board,  for  in  this  case  as  in  others  the 
board  refuses  to  adopt  any  higher  standard  than  that  set 
by  the  more  technical  local  department  and  here  again  the 
standard  is  low.  If  the  health  department,  on  the  other 
9 


I3O  THE  LABOR  LAW   OF   MARYLAND  [2/6 

hand,  finds  from  an  examination  of  the  records  and  report 
that  the  place  is  below  the  minimum,  the  license  is  with- 
held until  these  defects  are  remedied,  and  even  then  it  is 
not  issued  until  the  approval  of  the  health  department  is 
obtained. 

It  is  obvious  from  what  has  been  said  that  however  good 
this  law  may  be  in  its  substantive  provisions  and  however 
complete  may  be  the  records  obtained  under  this  act,  in  final 
results,  because  of  the  great  division  of  administrative  re- 
sponsibility and  the  inefficiency  of  the  personnel  to  which 
is  entrusted  the  enforcement,  the  law  fails  to  realize  a  large 
amount  of  its  potential  value. 

Next  in  importance  to  the  factory  inspection  law  is  the 
recent  child  labor  law.12  As  has  been  said  in  a  previous 
chapter,  this  is  a  most  valuable  act  and  in  draftsmanship 
one  of  the  best  on  the  statute  book.  The  act  goes  into  great 
detail  in  establishing  administrative  provisions  for  its  en- 
forcement and  an  exhaustive  study  might  profitably  be 
made  of  these  administrative  details ;  but  it  will  serve  our 
purpose  in  the  general  estimate  of  the  Maryland  system  of 
labor  law  administration  merely  to  point  out  the  salient 
features  of  these  administrative  provisions. 

After  the  inspections  under  the  factory  law,  the  next  duty 
of  the  inspectors  is  to  investigate  the  ages  and  conditions  of 
employment  of  children.  The  inspection  under  this  law 
should  be  more  efficient  than  under  the  law  which  we  have 
just  been  considering,  for  no  skill  is  required  and  no  tech- 
nical training  necessary.  Even  a  political  appointee  should 
be  able  to  prepare  a  complete  report.  The  task  of  the  in- 
spector is  merely  to  see  that  the  employer  complies  with 
certain  provisions,  such  as  the  keeping  of  a  registry,  to  ex- 
amine the  certificates  of  any  children  who  are  below  six- 
teen, to  ascertain  the  true  age  of  any  child  who  appears 
younger  than  sixteen,  the  employer  being  compelled  to  fur- 
nish within  fifteen  days  satisfactory  evidence  that  a  child 
apparently  under  sixteen  is  in  fact  over  sixteen  or  to  cease 

12  Laws  1912,  Ch.  731,  as  amended  in  1916. 


2/7]  THE   ADMINISTRATIVE   SYSTEM 

to  employ  that  child  ;13  and,  finally,  to  tabulate  the  number 
of  children  employed  in  the  various  occupations  in  the  fac- 
tory. If  any  child  is  employed  in  an  occupation  below  the 
age  which  the  law  provides,  the  inspector  will  notify  and 
warn  the  employer,  but  usually  prosecutions  and  the  pre- 
liminaries are  managed  from  the  home  office.  One  of  the 
child  labor  inspectors  under  the  old  bureau  had  in  practice 
been  found  to  be  more  efficient  than  the  others  and  she  had 
been  assigned  to  investigational  work  similar  to  that  per- 
formed by  the  British  lady  inspectors.  One  section  of  the 
law14  prohibits  the  employment  of  children  under  sixteen  in 
certain  specified  employments  or  "in  any  other  occupation 
dangerous  to  life  and  limb,  or  injurious  to  the  health  or 
morals  of  such  child."  Instead  of  leaving  the  interpreta- 
tion of  this  section  to  the  discretion  of  the  individual  in- 
spector, the  bureau  had  assigned  this  more  efficient  inspector 
to  the  work  of  ascertaining  what  are  dangerous  occupations 
and  was  to  issue  administrative  orders  on  the  basis  of  this 
investigation.  This  was  really  a  notable  step  in  advance 
and  fuller  mention  will  be  made  of  it  later.  It  is  to  be 
hoped  that  it  will  be  developed  further  by  the  state  board. 
The  task  of  issuing  employment  certificates  and  street 
trade  badges  is  a  somewhat  heavy  one  and  when  the  act 
first  went  into  force  the  offices  of  the  old  bureau  were 
Swamped  with  applicants.  Detailed  provisions  are  made 
in  the  act  as  to  the  requirements  which  must  be  fulfilled 
Before  these  permits  are  issued  and  granting  them  is  not  an 
indiscriminate,  clerical  operation.  In  Baltimore  City  the 
jboard  is  empowered  to  issue  these  employment  certificates, 
and  in  the  counties  the  county  superintendent  of  schools  has 
concurrent  jurisdiction  with  it.  In  the  offices  of  the  state 
board  there  is  a  special  inspector  at  a  higher  salary,  whose 
only  work  is  to  issue  these  certificates  and  to  keep  a  file  of 
the  duplicates.  The  two  physicians,  also,  earn  their  pay 
merely  by  examining  applicants  for  certificates.  The  re- 
is  Ibid.,  Sec.  19. 
« Ibid.,  Sec.  8. 


132  THE   LABOR   LAW   OF   MARYLAND  [278 

ports  of  these  examinations  promise  to  become  valuable 
.sociological  statistics.  In  reality,  the  board  issues  the  great 
majority  of  the  employment  certificates  for  city  and  coun- 
ties ;  but  when  the  school  superintendent  issues  a  certificate 
in  one  of  the  counties  he  is  empowered  to  employ  a  physi- 
cian at  a  stipulated  fee  to  make  the  examination  and  is  re- 
quired to  transmit  all  records  to  the  board.  One  of  the 
child  labor  inspectors  is  detailed  to  take  charge  of  the  issu- 
ing of  badges  to  boys  under  sixteen  engaged  in  street  trade. 

Both  in  administrative  provisions  and  administrative 
practice  this  is  one  of  the  most  satisfactory  and  efficient 
laws  in  the  Maryland  labor  code.  Nevertheless,  there  is  one 
defect,  perhaps  practically  unavoidable.  This  law  and  the 
compulsory  school  attendance  law  dovetail  exactly  and,  in 
fact,  the  enforcement  of  these  laws  is  indiscriminately  con- 
fided to  attendance  officers  and  inspectors  from  the  State 
Board  of  Labor  and  Statistics.  The  attendance  officers  and 
the  inspectors  are  responsible  and  report  to  different  chiefs 
who  are  themselves  in  no  way  related  and  have  no  official 
correspondence.  It  seems  that  here  a  valuable  opportunity 
to  check  up  results  has  been  lost. 

The  other  inspection  law  enforced  by  the  state  board,  the 
women's  ten-hour  law,15  has  no  interesting  administrative 
features.  The  inspector  merely  notices  that  the  substan- 
jtive  provisions  of  the  law,  such  as  the  posting  of  schedules, 
are  obeyed.  This  law,  for  political  reasons,  was  formerly 
enforced  by  a  special  bureau  composed  only  of  women. 
One  of  the  most  obvious  reforms  of  the  1916  amendment 
,was  the  placing  of  the  administration  of  this  law  under  the 
supervision  of  the  same  agency  which  enforced  the  child 
|abor  law. 

Two  other  inspection  laws  were  brought  under  the  in- 
direct control  of  the  State  Board  of  Labor  and  Statistics 
by  the  1916  legislature.  The  board  with  the  approval  of  the 
governor  appoints  two  boiler  inspectors  for  Baltimore  City18 

15  Laws  1912,  Ch.  79,  as  amended  in  1914  and  1916. 

16  Baltimore  City  Charter  1915,  Sees.  572-589,  as  amended  by  Laws 
1916,  Ch.  207. 


2/9]  THE  ADMINISTRATIVE  SYSTEM  133 

jand  a  mine  inspector  for  Alleghany  and  one  for  Garrett 
County.17  Aside  from  this  power  of  appointment  and  the 
fact  that  the  board  supplies  the  boiler  inspectors  with  office 
rooms  and  receives  annual  reports  from  these  officers,  there 
js  no  coordination  between  these  separate  agencies.  The 
legislature  attempted  to  introduce  a  centralized  system,  but 
merely  centralized  the  structure,  not  the  system.  The  boiler 
inspection  and  the  mine  inspection  laws  have  not  been 
changed  by  the  amalgamation.  The  inspectors  under  these 
Jaws  are  also  political  appointees,  but  the  mine  inspectors 
must  "possess  a  competent  and  practical  knowledge  of  the 
different  systems  of  mining  and  [ventilation]  .  .  .  and  of 
the  nature  and  constituent  parts  of  the  various  gases  found 
an  coal  mines  .  .  .  and  shall  have  had  five  years'  practical 
experience  as  a  miner/'  In  his  reports  he  is  to  make  rec- 
ommendations for  future  legislation  for  safety  in  mining.18 

Finally,  every  physician  attending  a  patient  suffering 
from  any  occupational  disease  must  make  a  full  report  to 
the  state  board  which  publishes  the  results  in  its  annual 
report.19  Though  a  minor  provision,  it  has  possibilities  and 
already  the  reports  make  interesting  reading. 

State  Board  of  Health. — Related  to  the  work  of  the  board 
of  labor  is  the  work  of  the  State  Board  of  Health  in  enforc- 
ing the  Sanitary  Inspection  Law.20  This  law  applies  only 
to  shops  and  factories  manufacturing  or  handling  food 
stuffs  and,  as  the  bureau  has  nothing  to  do  with  these  shops 
except  so  far  as  they  may  be  located  in  tenements  or  lofts, 
there  is  not  much  overlapping  in  inspection.  But,  logically, 
why  should  not  this  law  be  placed  under  the  charge  of  the 
State  Board  of  Labor  and  Statistics,  perhaps  assisted  by  the 
State  Board  of  Health? 

The  Sanitary  Inspection  Law,  as  will  be  remembered, 
lays  down  numerous  and  definite  specifications  for  the  clean- 

17  Code  Public  Local  Laws  1888,  Art  I,  Sec.  196,  and  Art.  12,  Sec. 
150,  as  amended  by  Laws  1902,  Ch.  124,  and  Laws  1916,  Ch.  410. 

18  Laws  1916,  Ch.  410. 
"Laws  1912,  Ch.  165,  Sec.  5 A. 
20  Laws  1914,  Ch.  678. 


134  THE  LABOR   LAW   OF   MARYLAND  [280 

liness  and  sanitary  condition  of  factories  or  shops  handling 
food  stuffs  and  more  stringent  rules  for  canneries.  It  is  a 
most  carefully  and  scientifically  drafted  law.  It  may  safely 
be  said  to  be  in  the  highest  rank  among  what  may  be  called 
regulative  acts,  a  class  of  laws  which,  however,  is  giving 
way  to  general  laws  with  provisions  for  administrative  or- 
ders. The  Maryland  law  does  indeed  include  a  provision 
for  these  orders;  but,  not  being  absolutely  essential  to  the 
working  of  the  act,  none  have  been  issued.  The  inspectors 
of  the  State  Board  of  Health  have,  then,  for  their  guidance 
in  the  administration  of  the  law  the  specifications  included 
within  the  body  of  the  law  and  nothing  else.  True,  these 
specifications  are  rather  searching  and  well-defined,  but  it 
is  impossible  that  even  the  legislature  could  have  foreseen 
all  the  contingencies  in  which  the  law  might  be  called  into 
play.  Accordingly,  with  respect  to  details  too  minute  to 
refer  to  the  Board  of  Health,  numerous  disputes  as  to  the 
interpretation  and  application  of  the  act  must  arise.  The 
inspector  is  thrown  back  upon  his  own  discretion  and  the 
law  is  strictly  or  loosely  enforced  according  to  the  tempera- 
ment of  the  inspector.  Now  it  has  not  been  possible  for 
me  to  interview  the  employers  affected  by  this  law,  but  from 
the  class  of  inspectors  who  are  employed  by  the  Board  of 
Health  it  would  seem  a  fair  deduction  that  the  act  is  admin- 
istered leniently  rather  than  strictly. 

The  full  control  over  the  administration  of  this  act  has 
been  placed  by  the  Board  of  Health  practically  in  the  hands 
of  one  member  of  that  board,  who  has  also  charge  of  the 
enforcement  of  the  Pure  Food  and  Drugs  Act.  He  com- 
bines the  work  of  enforcing  the  two  laws  and  uses  the  same 
inspectoral  force  for  both.  There  are  six  inspectors 
scattered  over  the  State.  Owing  to  the  fact  that  their 
work  as  pure  food  insepctors  necessitates  keeping  their 
identity  unknown  so  far  as  possible,  it  is  the  endeavor  of 
the  supervisor  to  have  the  same  man  visit  a  factory  at  r*s 
infrequent  intervals  as  possible.  The  inspections  are  fre- 
quent, about  four  a  year,  but  the  continual  switching  around 


28 1]  THE  ADMINISTRATIVE  SYSTEM  135 

of  inspectors  offsets  to  a  great  degree  the  advantages  to  be 
gained  from  frequent  inspections,  among  the  most  impor- 
tant of  which  are  the  familiarity  of  the  inspector  with  the 
plant  and  his  personal  amicable  relations  with  the  owner. 
It  may  be  said  here  that  the  Board  of  Health  is  noted  as 
being  of  the  various  State  departments  one  of  those  least 
contaminated  by  politics,  and  the  inspectors  may  be  efficient 
so  far  as  the  Pure  Food  Law  is  concerned,  in  connection 
with  which  all  the  technical  work  is  done  at  headquarters. 
An  inspector,  however,  who  has  no  technical  training,  whose 
salary  ranges  in  the  neighborhood  of  one  thousand  dollars, 
for  whom  there  is  little  or  no  hope  of  promotion,  and  who 
has  no  assurances  of  permanency  of  employment,  is  not 
one  to  whom  should  be  entrusted  the  enforcement  of  pro- 
visions calling  for  the  cleanliness  "  which  the  nature  of  the 
employment  will  permit "  or  the  detection  of  communicable 
diseases.  The  act  suffers  both  in  the  nature  of  the  admin- 
istration and  in  the  class  of  inspectors  to  whom  its  enforce- 
ment is  entrusted. 

Minor  Administrative  Agencies. — The  Industrial  Acci- 
dent Commission,  which  is  charged  with  the  administra- 
tion of  the  workmen's  compensation  law,  may  be  dismissed 
with  the  statement  that  it  is  wholly  separated  from  all 
other  labor  law  agencies  in  the  State.  Likewise  separated 
from  any  other  agency  is  the  Baltimore  City  Commissioner 
of  Health  in  his  performance  of  the  duty  imposed  upon 
him  to  inspect  all  mercantile  or  manufacturing  establish- 
ments in  Baltimore  City  where  females  are  employed  to 
see  that  seats  are  provided  for  these  employees21 — a  need- 
less overlapping  upon  the  Women's  Ten  Hour  Law  inspec- 
tion. Similarly  isolated  and  overlapping,  the  constable  of 
Carroll  County  inspects  the  ventilation  in  stone  grinding 
mills22 — certainly  an  incongruous  agency  for  the  adminis- 
tration of  labor  laws.  Hardly  less  so,  however,  are  the 


"Ordinances  of  Baltimore,  1910-1911,  No.  547. 

12  T  -in-c    T8/-H      PVi     trta 


*2  Laws  1894,  Ch.  202. 


136  THE   LABOR  LAW   OF   MARYLAND  [282 

marshals  of  police  or  the  police  commissioners  in  their  in- 
spection of  scaffoldings  which  are  reported  to  be  unsafe.28 

Suggestions  for  Reforms. — All  the  administrative  agen- 
cies charged  with  the  enforcement  of  the  Maryland  labor 
law  have  now  been  described  or  mentioned.  On  the  whole 
there  is  little  less  than  absolute  chaos.  One  department  is 
fairly  well  defined,  but,  on  the  whole,  no  more  cohesion  or 
system  is  present  than  in  a  pan  of  peas.  And  yet  the  situa- 
tion is  not  altogether  hopeless.  Other  States  have  evolved 
an  orderly  administration  out  of  equally  or  more  chaotic 
labor  laws  upon  a  critical  expose  of  that  condition.  It  is 
hoped  that  this  criticism  by  merely  reporting  the  results  in 
other  States  may  lead  to  some  such  result  in  Maryland. 

The  first  and  cheapest  reform  needed  is  some  method  of 
taking  the  personnel  of  the  various  departments  out  of  poli- 
tics. Much  has  already  been  said  of  the  disastrous  results 
of  the  present  methods  of  appointments  to  all  positions  in 
the  administration,  so  that  only  one  instance  further  will 
be  cited.  In  1915  the  elections  for  governor  occurred  on 
the  second  of  November  and  the  term  of  office  began  on 
January  I,  1916.  A  Democratic  governor  was  elected  to 
succeed  a  Republican.  A  week  after  the  November  elec- 
tion I  visited  the  Bureau  of  Statistics,  as  it  then  was,  to  in- 
terview the  assistant-chief.  It  was  only  half-past  two  in 
the  afternoon,  yet  there  was  not  a  single  man  in  the  office. 
All  the  inspectors  were  Republicans  and  knew  or  thought 
that  they  would  lose  their  positions  at  the  first  of  the  year, 
so  they  had  practically  refused  to  do  any  work  at  all. 
,  It  is  perfectly  obvious  that  some  sort  of  civil  service  ap- 
pointment is  the  prime  essential  to  an  efficient  administra- 
tion of  the  labor  law.  Whether  this  shall  be  by  competi- 
tive, technical  examination  or  by  qualifying,  general  exami- 
nation with  appointment  vested  in  the  head  of  the  labor 
department  is  a  question  somewhat  outside  the  scope  of  this 
study.  The  former  has  the  advantage  of  securing  techni- 
cally efficient  inspectors  substantially  freed  from  the  taint 

23  Code  1911,  Art.  48,  Sees.  75-79- 


283]  THE  ADMINISTRATIVE  SYSTEM  137 

of  politics ;  the  latter  the  advantage  of  securing  all  around 
efficient  inspectors  who  are  also  more  subservient  to  and 
often  also  more  agreeable  to  the  chiefs.  The  competitive 
examination  is  perhaps  more  suited  to  the  present  status  of 
labor  departments  where  there  is  a  subdivision  of  functions 
and  where  the  inspectors  are  selected  for  one  purpose  alone 
without  much  hope  of  promotion.  The  qualifying  exami- 
nation is  more  suited  to  the  centralized  system  which  has 
been  adopted  wherever  reform  has  been  introduced,  where 
the  inspector  has  various  duties  to  perform  in  an  inspectoral 
way,  where  he  must  be  acceptable  in  appearance  and  man- 
ner to  the  employers,  and  where,  moreover,  as  will  soon  be 
seen,  the  appointment  is  guarded  from  politics  by  the  na- 
ture of  the  head  of  the  department. 

In  addition  to  a  civil  service  appointment,  some  means 
must  be  provided  to  attract  the  desirable. classes  to  the  posi- 
tions in  the  service.  We  can  never  in  America  hope  to  in- 
spire in  our  citizens  the  regard  for  government  service 
which  is  present  in  the  German,  or  perhaps  even  in  the 
English,  heart ;  but  there  is  no  reason  why  the  government 
service  should  not  be  lifted  to  a  higher  plane  than  that 
which  it  now  occupies.  Salaries  in  the  United  States 
compare  most  favorably  with  those  abroad,  so  that  there  is 
not  much  room  for  improvement  in  this  direction  without 
involving  great  expense.  Improvement  is  needed  in  re- 
spect to  the  security  of  tenure,  the  opportunities  for  ad- 
vancement, and  the  provisions  for  the  disabilities  of  age  or 
accident.  We  have  referred  in  the  preceding  chapter 
apropos  of  the  Massachusetts  state  pension  law  to  the  value 
of  a  pension  system  for  state  employees  as  an  incentive  to 
efficient  administration;  but  nowhere  in  the  United  States 
does  there  seem  to  have  been  a  proper  appreciation  of  per- 
manency and  promotion  as  essentials  in  government  employ- 
ment. It  is  useless  to  press  a  priori  arguments.  In  the 
light  of  the  wonderful  success  of  the  English  system  of  gov- 
ernment in  general,  one  may  demand,  in  the  administration 


138  THE   LABOR   LAW   OF   MARYLAND  [284 

of  the  labor  law,  a  graded  system  of  inspectors  with  pro- 
motion for  efficiency  and  permanency  of  service. 

Nevertheless,  such  a  statement  of  the  principles  of  ad- 
ministration calls  for  some  qualification.  There  must  be 
considered  the  inevitable  conflict  of  an  independent,  bureau- 
cratic administration  and  a  politically  responsible  adminis- 
tration. Abstract  questions  would  lead  us  too  far  afield; 
so,  concretely,  should  the  heads  of  the  various  departments 
•be  selected  absolutely  by  the  governor  or  should  there  be 
promotion  from  the.  ranks  ?  As  the  labor  administration  is 
now  constituted,  it  would  seem  perfectly  feasible  to  vest 
the  selection  of  the  entire  force  in  a  civil  service  board.  The 
only  reason  for  the  political  appointment  of  the  various 
chiefs  would  be  to  secure  uniformity  of  policy  and  politi- 
cal responsibility  and  neither  of  these  is  necessary  in  the 
Maryland  system:  the  only  policy  should  be  an  absolutely 
strict  adherence  to  the  terms  of  the  law,  and  removal  of 
the  chiefs  for  cause  by  the  governor  provides  all  the  respon- 
sibility which  could  reasonably  be  expected.  It  is  perhaps 
unfortunate  that  all  of  these  administrative  agencies  are 
directly  subordinated  to  the  governor  and  that  there  is  no 
intermediate  state  officer  responsible  for  them  to  the  gover- 
nor, but  this  deficiency  does  not  invalidate  the  proposal 
that  as  now  constituted  the  labor  administration  should  be 
entirely  divorced  from  politics.  Under  the  scheme  of  ad- 
ministration which  is  now  to  be  described,  however,  the 
present  heads  of  departments  would  be  merely  chiefs  of 
bureaus  who  could  be  efficiently  chosen  by  promotion  from 
the  ranks,  whereas  the  head  of  the  unified  department  of 
labor,  be  it  an  individual  or  a  commission,  would  be  selected 
by  and  responsible  to  the  governor.  Not  only  administra- 
tively but  also  politically  the  centralized  administrative  sys- 
tem is  the  more  desirable. 

What  has  been  termed  the  centralized  administrative 
system  has  only  recently  made  its  appearance  in  American 
labor  legislation.  Labor  legislation  in  the  United  States 
has  been  a  gradual  evolution  without  any  preconceived 


285]  THE  ADMINISTRATIVE   SYSTEM  139 

plan,  so  that  the  administrative  result  has  'been  a  hopeless 
hodge-podge.  Under  the  influence  of  the  movement  for 
efficiency,  several  States  have  recently  completely  reorgan- 
ized their  labor  law  administrations  into  logical,  central- 
ized systems.  This  reorganization  is  precisely  what  Mary- 
land needs.  Civil  service  reform  would  work  wonders 
with  that  vaguely  outlined  thing  which  has  up  till  now 
been  termed  the  Maryland  labor  department  or  labor  de- 
partments, but  to  obtain  real  efficiency  Maryland  should 
have  a  true  Labor  Department  embracing  all  the  adminis- 
trative agencies  enforcing  laws  throughout  the  State.  Such 
a  reform  would  involve  some  additional  expense,  but  ex- 
actly how  much  is  hard  to  calculate  because  there  would 
be  a  great  saving  in  the  elimination  of  overlapping  func- 
tions. Such  a  reform  would  place  some  additional  burden 
upon  the  legislature  which  initiates  it,  but,  in  establishing 
an  administrative  system  to  which  the  administration  of 
any  future  labor  law  might  in  a  few  words  be  referred,  it 
would  relieve  subsequent  legislatures.  The  investigating 
commissions  in  New  York  and  Illinois  have  recommended 
reorganization  of  this  kind,  and  sufficient  has  been  written 
about  it  to  enable  an  amateur  in  administration  to  suggest 
reforms  for  Maryland. 

The  reorganized  Maryland  Department  of  Labor  should 
be  presided  over  by  a  commissioner  or  commission  ap- 
pointed by  the  governor.  The  head  of  the  department 
should  be  the  only  position  filled  by  appointment.  His 
deputies,  if  there  are  any,  the  heads  of  the  various  bureaus, 
the  division  chiefs,  and  the  inspectors  would  be  selected  by 
the  merit  system.  In  this  way  the  English  administrative 
system  would  be  approximated,  that  is,  a  political  chief  with 
civil  subordinates.  If  sufficient  confidence  can  be  placed  in 
the  head  of  the  department,  he  should  be  given  the  power 
of  choosing  his  subordinates  from  a  list  of  qualified  appli- 
cants and  this  method  is  especially  applicable  to  the  chiefs 
of  bureaus  who  must  have  other  qualifications  than  those 
which  can  be  ascertained  by  examination.  Everything  pos- 


I4O  THE  LABOR   LAW   OF   MARYLAND  [286 

,sible  should  be  done  to  bring  about  a  condition  in  which 
the  head  of  the  department  will  be  fully  trusted ;  but,  if  he 
is  not,  appointment  to  all  subordinate  positions  should  be 
by  competitive  examination'. 

The  Department  of  Labor  should  be  divided  into  six 
bureaus :  the  bureau  of  inspection,  the  bureau  of  statistics 
and  information,  the  bureau  of  arbitration  and  mediation, 
the  bureau  of  mines,  the  employment  bureau,  and  the  indus- 
trial accident  commission.  The  bureau  of  inspection  would 
be  the  most  important  of  these  and  it  might  be  feasible  in 
the  present  condition  of  the  labor  law  to  put  in  charge  of 
this  bureau  the  Commissioner  of  Labor  himself  with  the 
aid  of  a  deputy  if  necessary. 

The  bureau  of  inspection  should  be  divided  into  five  di- 
visions :  the  division  of  factory  inspection,  the  division  of 
home-work  inspection,  the  division  of  mercantile  inspection, 
the  division  of  steam  boiler  inspection,  and  the  division  of 
industrial  hygiene.  It  may  be  objected  that  this  subdivision 
is  too  minute  for  present  conditions  in  Maryland.  To  a 
certain  degree  the  objection  is  valid :  some  of  the  divisions 
may  have  little  to  do  and  one  man  may  be  sufficient  to  fill 
them.  This  plan,  however,  is  not  to  meet  present  condi- 
tions only,  but  is  to  furnish  a  basis  for  all  future  labor  leg- 
islation, and  we  may  be  .sure  that  future  labor  legislation 
will  be  quantitatively  greater  than  in  the  past.  One  of  the 
first  duties  of  the  legislature  after  reorganizing  the  admin- 
istration should  be  to  make  some  of  the  local  laws  state- 
wide, for  in  the  main  they  seem  to  have  been  enacted 
locally  because  of  the  lack  of  state-wide  administrative 
agencies.  Now  the  inspectors  in  the  factory,  home-work, 
and  mercantile  divisions  will  all  enforce  practically  the 
same  laws.  The  divisions  will  be  upon  the  basis  of  places 
inspected  instead  of  laws  enforced,  and  every  inspector  will 
be  authorized  to  enforce  any  law  which  is  applicable  to  the 
establishment  which  he  is  visiting.  Moreover,  entire  au- 
thority to  enforce  the  laws  must  be  centralized  in  the  Labor 
Department  and  all  reference  to  local  authorities  must  be 


28/j  THE  ADMINISTRATIVE   SYSTEM  14! 

discontinued;  the  Labor  Department  must  be  made  self- 
sufficient.  Thus  practically  all  overlapping  will  be  elimi- 
nated. 

Of  sufficient  importance  to  be  entitled  to  special  mention 
is  the  division  of  industrial  hygiene,  copied  from  the  New 
York  division  of  the  same  name.2*  It  is  what  is  popularly 
known  as  a  bureau  of  "theorists,"  a  bureau  of  technical 
experts,  being  composed  in  New  York  of  a  physician,  a 
chemical  engineer,  a  mechanical  engineer  who  is  an  expert 
in  ventilation  and  accident  prevention,  and  a  civil  engineer 
who  is  an  expert  in  fire  prevention  and  building  construc- 
tion. The  duty  of  this  division  is  to  make  inspections  of  a 
highly  technical  nature,  to  make  independent  investigations 
upon  which  laws  and  orders  may  be  issued,  and  to  serve  as 
general  technical  advisors  to  the  department.  This  is  an 
expensive  division,  but  it  is  a  most  valuable  one.  It  would 
be  well  if  Maryland  could  copy  the  New  York  plan  in  its 
entirety,  but  that  is  not  a  necessity.  To  begin  with,  Mary- 
land would  need  at  least  one  physician  to  supervise  the  issu- 
ing of  child-labor  permits  and  the  inspection  of  food- 
producing  establishments.  The  mechanical  engineer  would 
be  a  valuable  adjunct  to  the  Industrial  Accident  Commis- 
sion and  the  State  Insurance  Fund. 

The  other  bureaus  are  less  important.  The  bureau  of 
statistics  and  information  should  have  the  same  functions 
that  that  bureau  originally  exercised ;  it  should  be  the  pub- 
licity bureau  of  the  department.  The  bureau  of  arbitration 
and  mediation  should  have  the  enforcement  of  the  law 
which  is  now  entrusted  to  the  State  Board  of  Labor,  to- 
gether with  the  enforcement  of  any  more  efficient  law 
which  might  be  enacted.  The  bureau  of  mines  should  be 
charged  with  the  enforcement  of  the  mining  law  in  the 
western  counties.  The  bureau  of  employment  should  be 
charged  with  the  establishment  of  free  employment  offices 
and  the  licensing  of  private  employment  offices.  The  In- 

24  New  York  Consolidated  Laws,  Ch.  31,  Art  4,  Sec.  60,  as  amended 
in  1913.  Laws  1913,  Ch.  145. 


142  THE  LABOR  LAW   OF   MARYLAND  [288 

dustrial  Accident  Commission,  which  has  been  placed  as 
the  sixth  bureau  in  the  Labor  Department,  should  hold  a 
relation  to  the  department  entirely  different  from  the  other 
bureaus.  For  a  number  of  reasons  it  is  advisable  that  there 
be  some  connection  between  this  commission  and  the  rest 
of  the  department;  but,  owing  to  the  importance  of  the 
commission  and  the  class  of  men  who  are  necessary  for  the 
adequate  administration  of  the  compensation  law,  it  is 
doubtful  if  the  commissioners  should  be  made  more  than 
nominally  subordinate  to  the  head  of  the  department  or  if 
they  should  be  chosen  in  the  same  manner  as  are  the  chiefs 
of  the  other  bureaus.  This  is  a  practical  question  calling 
for  fuller  discussion  than  can  be  given  it  here. 

The  question  whether  the  administrative  head  of  the 
Department  of  Labor  should  be  an  individual  or  a  commis- 
sion has  been  complicated  in  most  States  where  reorganiza- 
tion has  taken  place  by  questions  of  legislative  policy.  Most 
of  these  States  have  enacted  generaL  laws,  with  delegated 
authority  to  issue  specific  orders,  to  take  the  place  of  the 
detailed  and  intricate  laws  on  their  statute  books.  Enough 
has  already  been  said  of  the  advantages  of  this  mode  of  leg- 
islation both  from  the  substantive  and  the  administrative 
standpoint.  From  the  point  of  view  of  administration,  the 
elimination  of  all  discretion  in  the  individual  inspector  and 
the  substitution  of  the  educational,  helpful  attitude  for  the 
antagonistic,  prosecuting  frame  of  mind  are  advantages  so 
manifest  as  to  be  undeniable. 

For  purely  executive  work,  a  one-man  head  is  most  de- 
sirable, but  if  the  head  of  the  department  has  ordinance 
powers  some  sort  of  commission  is  a  logical  necessity.  Up 
to  the  present  time  there  have  been  devised  four  forms 
which  this  commission  might  take.  In  the  first  place,  the 
Wisconsin  plan  places  all  the  power,  executive  as  well  as 
administrative,  in  the  hands  of  a  commission  of  three,  an 
excellent  plan  in  most  respects,  but  it  has  not  been  followed 
and  has  been  much  criticised  because  of  the  weakness  in- 
herent in  the  division  of  executive  authority.  The  second 


289]  THE  ADMINISTRATIVE   SYSTEM  143 

plan  is  the  New  York  scheme  adopted  in  1913  under  which 
there  is  a  single  executive  head,  the  commissioner,  and  an 
advisory  board  of  representative  men  and  women  not  subor- 
dinate to,  but  presided  over  by,  the  commissioner,  which  is 
empowered  to  draft  orders.  The  objection  urged  against 
this  plan  is  that  which  is  urged  against  all  part-time  boards, 
the  objection  of  inefficiency.  In  the  third  place,  a  slight 
variation  of  the  New  York  plan  is  advocated,  the  single 
executive  head  as  before,  but  a  commission  composed  of  the 
chiefs  of  bureaus.  This  is  open  to  the  serious  objection  that 
it  confers  independent  advisory  and  discretionary  functions 
upon  officers  who  are  administratively  subordinate  to  the 
head  of  the  department  and  who  are,  moreover,  civil  ser- 
vice appointees  with  technical  proficiency,  but  hardly  legis- 
latively representative.  The  final  plan  is  that  advocated 
by  the  Illinois  Efficiency  Commission  of  1914.  This  retains 
the  single  commissioner  and  associates  with  him  two  depu- 
ties, free  from  executive  duties  and  of  equal  rank  with  the 
commissioner  so  far  as  ordinance  power  is  concerned. 
Aside  from  the  possibility  of  friction,  the  overwhelming 
objection  to  this  scheme  is  the  useless  multiplication  of 
officers  for  an  administration  the  size  of  Maryland's. 

On  the  whole  it  would  seem  that  the  New  York  plan, 
which  has  been  adopted  in  a  modified  form  by  the  1916 
amendment,  is  best  adapted  to  the  needs  of  Maryland.  Be- 
sides the  commissioner,  the  board  is  composed  of  four  mem- 
bers, of  whom  it  is  advisable  that  one  should  be  an  em- 
ployer of  labor,  one  a  wage-earner,  one  a  physician  or  sani- 
tary engineer,  and  one  a  woman.  All  of  these  offices  should 
be  filled  by  appointment  by  the  governor  and  the  salaries 
should  be  large  enough  to  be  attractive  to  the  worthy  and 
the  influential.  For  the  conduct  of  its  business  the  board 
should  meet  once  or  twice  a  month  at  the  call  of  the  com- 
missioner. Besides  the  work  of  formulating  administrative 
ordinances,  the  commissioner  should  lay  before  the  board 
all  matters  in  which  any  policy  or  discretion  is  involved, 
except  as  the  exigencies  of  a  particular  case  may  call  for 


144  THE  LABOR  LAW   OF   MARYLAND  [290 

immediate  action.  The  board  should  also  have  some  ad- 
visory power  in  the  choice  of  subordinates,  if  these  are 
selected  from  a  qualifying  and  not  from  a  competitive  ex- 
amination. In  general,  however,  except  in  the  matter  of 
formulating  ordinances,  the  board  should  be  merely  advis- 
ory to  the  commissioner,  for  administrative  responsibility 
must  be  centered  in  one  man  and,  in  the  last  resort,  the 
commissioner  himself  must  be  directly  responsible  to  the 
governor.  Centralization  and  discretionary  power  must 
always  be  balanced  by  responsibility. 

This  brief  outline  I  have  built  up  almost  entirely  inde- 
pendently of  the  1916  reorganization  of  the  Maryland  labor 
administration,  the  form  of  the  head  of  the  department  and 
the  centralizing  idea  being  the  only  similarities.  I  have  been 
forced  to  do  this  for  the  reason  that  the  1916  amendment, 
although  a  good  beginning,  failed,  like  all  pervious  legisla- 
tion, to  take  a  large  and  comprehensive  view  of  the  situa- 
tion. As  has  been  said,  by  failing  to  go  all  the  way  it  failed 
to  realize  many  of  its  possibilities.  Instead  of  looking  to 
the  future,  the  legislature  only  strove  to  correct  some  of 
the  defects  of  the  past,  and  accordingly  future  legislatures 
will  have  almost  as  much  difficulty  in  attaching  new  duties 
to  the  state  board  as  it  did  to  the  old  bureau.  The  plan 
presented  in  this  chapter  is  based  upon  scientific  investiga- 
tions conducted  in  the  most  advanced  States ;  and  while  no 
scheme  can  be  unalterable,  this  one  has  been  elaborated 
with  as  much  prevision  as  mankind  is  capable  of. 


CHAPTER  VIII 
THE  STATE  IN  RELATION  TO  LABOR 

It  seems  rather  preposterous  after  the  description  of  the 
administration  of  the  Maryland  labor  law  given  in  the  last 
chapter  to  repeat  what  was  said  in  the  first  chapter,  that 
Maryland  is  an  average  American  State  so  far  as  its  labor 
law  is  concerned.  Yet  calmer  consideration  will  justify  this 
statement.  The  administration,  it  must  be  admitted,  is  in- 
ferior, though  the  system  of  administration  which  is  provided 
by  statute  might  be  made  comparatively  efficient.  Equally 
poor  are  the  safety  and  sanitary  inspection  laws  with  the 
exception  of  the  recent  sanitary  provisions  for  food  manu- 
facturing establishments.  Slightly  better  'are  the  laws  regu- 
lating the  terms  of  employment  of  adult  men,  though,  it 
must  be  remembered,  these  laws  have  far  from  justified 
their  enactment.  The  other  provisions  of  the  labor  law  are 
above  the  average.  The  child  labor  law  and  the  workmen's 
compensation  law,  though  perhaps  capable  of  improvement, 
are  really  exemplary  pieces  of  legislation.  The  industrial 
disputes  act  and  the  other  laws  relating  to  the  labor  union 
are  almost  as  good  as  could  be  hoped  for.  The  women's 
ten-hour  law  ranks  lower  than  similar  laws  in  many  States, 
but  nevertheless  Maryland  is  above  the  average.  The  non- 
statutory  law  of  the  labor  union,  while  not  ideal  and  not 
even  satisfactory  under  present  conditions,  is  in  absolute 
accord  with  the  best  legal  thought. 

In  spite  of  the  fact  that  Maryland  deserves  such  a  rank, 
a  general  survey  of  the  labor  law  is  likely  to  be  most  dis- 
appointing. The  labor  law  considered  as  a  whole  displays 
the  same  lack  of  system  that  was  evident  in  the  administra- 
tion of  that  law.  The  legislature  churns  out  haphazardly 
all  kinds  of  labor  law  and  when  the  student  tries  to  unearth 
10  145 


146  THE   LABOR  LAW  OF   MARYLAND  [2Q2 

some  maxims  or  some  philosophy  upon  which  the  legisla- 
tion is  based,  he  is  met  with  absolute  chaos.  Not  only  is 
this  chaos  present  in  the  legislative  enactments,  it  is  also 
only  too  evident  in  judicial  decisions.  Now,  we  could 
perhaps  excuse  the  legislatures  for  this  deficiency,  for  as 
our  state  legislatures  are  now  composed,  it  is  hardly  to  be 
expected  that  they  will  have  any  continuous  policy  of  legis- 
lation in  any  branch  of  state  activity ;  and,  in  respect  to  the 
labor  law,  they  respond  to  the  demands  of  their  constitu- 
ents just  in  proportion  as  the  proposed  measure  seems  a 
good  Vote-getting  device.  But  the  courts  which  exercise 
a  great  influence  upon  all  social  legislation  through  their 
power  to  declare  laws  unconstitutional  have  no  such  excuse. 
They  have  endeavored  in  some  cases  to  throw  the  blame 
for  reactionary  decisions  upon  the  counsel  who  argued  be- 
fore them,1  but  this  excuse — to  use  their  own  language — 
though  perhaps  evidence  of  extenuating  circumstances  does 
not  detract  from  the  weight  of  the  offense. 

When  I  say  that  neither  the  courts  nor  the  legislature  act 
upon  any  consistent  philosophy  of  labor  legislation,  I  am,  in 
one  sense,  not  speaking  with  strict  accuracy.  The  legislatures 
do  still  act  as  they  always  have  acted  upon  the  theory  that 
laws  which  are  strenuously  demanded  by  a  great  number 
are  desirable,  and  the  courts  have  formulated  a  maxim  that 
legislation  must  be  for  the  welfare  of  the  general  public  and 
not  of  a  particular  class.  Neither  of  these  principles,  how- 
ever, is  specific  enough  as  a  basis  for  legislation.  More 
concretely  the  courts  from  time  to  time  have  acted  upon  the 
principle  that  those  labor  laws  are  proper  which  tend  to 
equalize  the  bargaining  powers  of  labor  and  capital  or  upon 
the  principle  that  the  legislature  should  only  enact  laws  safe- 
guarding the  public  health,  morals  or  safety ;  but  neither  of 
these  principles  has  been  iterated  consistently  enough  to  be 
called  a  philosophy  of  the  courts.  There  is,  then,  in  labor 
legislation  only  the  philosophic  principle  of  individualism 

1  See  Ritchie  v.  Wayman,  244  111.  509 ;  People  v.  Schweinler,  53 
N.  Y.  L.  J.  81. 


293]        THE  STATE  IN  RELATION  TO  LABOR          147 

dating  back  to  Jeremy  Bentham  as  modified  by  present  con- 
ditions in  the  direction  of  state  intervention.  But  when  it 
is  remembered  that  the  exceptions  to  the  individualistic 
principles  are  more  numerous  than  the  rule,  that  the  tend- 
ency is  towards  state  intervention  and  away  from  laissez- 
faire,  it  will  be  obvious  that  some  limitation  upon  state 
action  is  necessary  unless  individualism  is  gradually  to 
change  to  socialism.  There  has  as  yet  been  formulated  by 
legislature  or  court  no  such  limiting  principle  and  the  result 
is  a  confused  and  chaotic  mass  of  labor  laws  obeying  no 
definite  rule  of  the  relation  of  the  state  to  labor. 

In  attempting  to  outline  any  system  of  philosophy  of  labor 
legislation,  we  must,  to  conserve  energy,  use  as  many  prin- 
ciples of  existing  theories  or  systems  as  is  possible.  Not 
only  does  such  a  plan  conserve  energy,  but  it  also  commends 
itself  in  lending  greater  plausibility  to  the  new  scheme. 
Before  outlining  our  scheme,  therefore,  it"  will  be  necessary 
to  extract  the  best  points  from  the  two  prevalent  philoso- 
phies of  state  activity,  laissez-faire  and  socialism. 

Laissez-faire,  as  has  been  said,  is  the  philosophy  of  com- 
plete inactivity  on  the  part  of  the  state.  Realizing  the  value 
of  individual  initiative,  the  believers  in  laissez-faire  advo~ 
cated  the  absolutely  unrestricted  development  of  this  vir- 
tue. So  sure  were  they  of  the  efficacy  of  this  quality  that 
they  were  content  to  conceive  the  welfare  of  the  state  as 
merely  the  sum  total  of  the  welfare  of  the  individuals 
composing  it.  Now  the  philosophy  of  individualism  is 
sound  in  so  far  as  it  accentuates  the  necessity  of  individual 
initiative  and  this  is  the  element  which  we  must  try  to 
preserve;  but  experience  soon  proved  that  its  corollary  of 
laissez-faire  was  an  impossible  solution  of  the  relation  of 
the  state  to  labor.  Laissez-faire  exalted  competition  with  a 
hope  of  weeding  out  the  unfit,  but  the  result  was  a  compe- 
tition between  classes  which  must  function  together  if  they 
are  to  attain  the  greatest  common  good.  Instead  of  com- 
petition weeding  out  the  unfit  and  raising  the  standards  of 
social  and  industrial  life,  unregulated  competition  lowered 


148  THE  LABOR   LAW   OF   MARYLAND  [294 

the  standards  to  the  basis  of  those  of  the  lowest  competitor. 
Not  only  did  the  individual  suffer,  but  the  community  and 
the  state  were  also  hurt  by  this  rampant  selfishness.  And 
the  state  suffers  both  from  the  individual  suffering  of  its 
citizens  and  from  the  torpidity  which  this  philosophy  forces 
upon  it.  Individual  initiative  should  be  fostered,  but  selfish- 
ness must  be  carefully  repressed. 

As  a  reaction  against  this  theory  of  the  relation  of  the 
state  to  its  citizen,  there  came  into  being  the  political  phi- 
losophy of  socialism.  This  philosophy,  as  I  view  it — and 
there  are  almost  as  many  views  of  socialism  as  there  are 
socialists — is  the  result  of  the  theory  that  thinking  men 
"no  longer  hope  for  salvation  through  'the  free  play  of 
individual  interests,'  and  '  freedom  of  contract '  .  .  .  they 
are  apt  to  identify  the  cause  of  liberty  with  a  policy  of 
social  injustice.  .  .  .  The  real  test  of  liberty  is  to  be  found 
less  in  the  form  of  government  or  in  the  number  of  laws 
that  control  the  action  of  the  citizen  than  in  the  extent  to 
which  the  citizen  is  assured  the  means  of  self-realization.'*2 
So  far  again  we  may  accept  the  tenets  of  this  theory,  but 
the  complete  socialistic  program  of  state  activity  goes  on 
to  advocate  at  the  least  the  socialization  of  all  the  means  of 
production.  That  is,  socialism  in  opposition  to  laissez-faire 
believes  in  the  most  intimate  intervention  of  the  state  in  the 
life  of  its  citizens,  intervention  extending  as  far  as  state 
control,  if  not  ownership,  of  all  the  factories,  land,  trans- 
portation, and  other  productive  agencies.  Socialism  by  the 
logical  development  of  its  fundamental  tenet  departs  quite 
as  completely  as  does  individualism  from  its  original  con- 
cept. Socialism  in  endeavoring  to  assure  to  the  citizen  the 
means  of  self-realization  by  a  complete  system  of  liberty- 
making  restrictions  ends  by  completely  stifling  individual 
initiative.  This  in  the  last  analysis  is  the  real  argument 
against  socialism;  it  involves  the  rule  of  a  bureaucracy  in 
political  and  industrial  affairs,  a  superabundance  of  laws 
which  inevitably  tend  to  deteriorate  in  quality  as  they  in- 

2  W.  Jethro  Brown,  Underlying  Principles  of  Legislation,  p.  57  ff. 


295]        THE  STATE  IN  RELATION  TO  LABOR         149 

crease  in  quantity,  and  a  too  frequent  interference  of  the 
administrative  powers  of  the  state  in  the  life  of  the  citizen 
— all  this  at  the  expense  of  a  proper  encouragement  of  the 
vitally  necessary  individual  initiative.  If  a  socialism  could 
be  conceived  which  would  preserve  this  one  quality,  it  would 
be  desirable  in  spite  of  its  other  faults ;  but  so  far  no  such 
conception  has  been  formulated. 

We  can  then  begin  our  constructive  philosophy  upon 
these  two  fundamental  ideas  which  have  now  received 
rather  general  acceptance,  the  ideas  that  individual  initia- 
tive and  self-realization  must  be  stimulated  and  that  a 
proper  use  of  legislation  can  be  made  to  contribute  to  this 
end.  Individual  initiative  is  essential  to  progress,  but  in- 
dividualism untempered  by  state  interference  is  an  im- 
possible principle.  The  state  must  interfere  when  individ- 
ualism fails  to  achieve  the  greatest  common  good;  but  the 
state  should  interfere  as  rarely  as  possible,  state  interven- 
tion should  be  always  the  secondary  consideration.  As 
Schaffle  says  of  the  need  of  state  intervention  in  the  protec- 
tion of  labor:  "It  [the  state]  only  steps  in  when  self-help 
and  mutual  help,  supplemented  by  ordinary  state  protec- 
tion, fail  to  meet  the  exigencies  of  the  situation,  whether 
momentarily  and  on  account  of  special  circumstances,  or  by 
the  necessities  of  the  case."3  The  state's  policy  of  inter- 
vention should  be  not  only  temperate,  but  as  far  as  pos- 
sible uniform.  That  is,  the  state  should  not  manifest  itself 
too  variously  in  differentiated  classes  of  laws,  but  should 
strive  to  specialize  its  activity.  One  of  the  causes  of  the 
failure  of  socialism  is  that  the  state  is  called  upon  to  at- 
tempt duties  too  diversified.  The  state  promotes  individual 
initiative  most  effectively  by  confining  itself  as  nearly  as 
possible  to  its  prime  duty  of  policing,  and  all  its  activity 
should  be  closely  related  to  this  fundamental  activity.  Its 
legislation  to  make  real  the  theoretical  liberty  which  the 
laissez-faire  philosophers  believed  in  should  be  legislation 
which  really  makes  the  individual  capable  of  caring  for  him- 

8  Schaffle,  Labor  Protection,  p.  n. 


I5O  THE   LABOR   LAW   OF   MARYLAND  [296 

self,  not  legislation  which  attempts  to  take  care  of  the 
individual. 

With  these  fundamental  principles  in  mind,  let  us  con- 
sider the  existing  labor  conditions.  We  have  traced  in  the 
first  chapter  the  varying  development  of  the  theories  of 
labor  law  and  it  was  pointed  out  that  not  until  the  last 
period  of  this  development,  the  period  of  laissez-faire  miti- 
gated by  legislation  in  favor  of  the  laborer,  was  the  labor 
problem  serious  enough  to  merit  activity  upon  the  part  of 
the  state  purely  in  solution  of  this  problem.  Moreover,  it 
was  there  also  shown  that  this  last  period  dated  from  soon 
after  the  Industrial  Revolution.  These  two  facts  are  not 
chance  concomitants ;  they  have  a  real  relation  to  the  prob- 
lem. Prior  to  the  Industrial  Revolution,  the  employer  and 
employee  were  in  intimate  personal  relation  to  each  other. 
The  employer  employed  few  men  and  usually  did  part  of 
the  manual  labor  himself.  He  usually  knew  the  conditions 
of  these  men  and  took  an  interest  in  their  welfare.  More- 
over, the  men  were  able  to  bargain  successfully  for  their 
own  welfare,  for  the  employee  had  almost  as  many  shops 
in  which  to  seek  employment  as  the  employers  had  occa- 
sions to  employ  workmen.  In  other  words,  the  business 
unit  was  so  small  that  the  individual  employer  had  no 
greater  monopoly  of  jobs  than  the  employee  had  of  work- 
ing ability.  After  the  Industrial  Revolution,  however,  one 
employer  employed  hundreds  and  thousands  of  workmen. 
Not  only  did  he  have  greater  experience  in  hiring  labor 
than  the  employee  had  in  seeking  work,  but  because  of  the 
magnitude  of  his  business  he  had  more  of  a  monopoly  of 
the  jobs  obtainable.  Briefly,  the  employer  had  what  the 
employee  wanted  most  of  all — work;  he  usually  was  not 
hard  put  to  it  to  get  what  the  employee  had — labor ;  he  was 
in  a  superior  economic  position  and  had  more  experience  in 
making  the  contract  of  employment.  The  individual  em- 
ployee was  practically  at  the  mercy  of  the  employer;  the 
employer  set  the  conditions  of  employment  and  the  em- 
ployee was  compelled  to  acquiesce  in  them. 


THE  STATE  IN  RELATION  TO  LABOR  !$! 

As  an  offset  to  this  inequality  of  bargaining  power,  the 
workman  evolved  the  old  craft  gild  into  the  labor  union. 
By  thus  combining  the  individuals  in  a  particular  craft  into 
an  organized  whole  and  developing  one  of  the  members  into 
a  trained  bargainer,  the  employees  were  able  to  balance  the 
monopoly  and  the  experience  of  the  employer.  Collective 
bargaining  for  the  whole  union  was  substituted  for  the  in- 
dividual bargaining  of  the  single  employee.  But  this  solu- 
tion has  not  been  adequate.  It  was  because  unionism  was 
incomplete,  however,  not  because  it  was  ineffective,  that 
the  state  was  compelled  to  legislate.  The  state  soon  discov- 
ered that  it  had  to  interfere  in  the  labor  contract ;  absolute 
laissez-faire  was  not  feasible  under  a  factory  system  of  in- 
dustry and  an  unorganized  community  of  laborers.  The 
more  powerful  employer,  it  was  found,  used  his  power 
selfishly  to  the  detriment  of  the  state.  The  state  recognized 
the  inequality  of  the  bargaining  power  of  the  two  parties 
to  the  contract  and  stepped  in  to  remedy  the  effects  of  this 
inequality.  Would  it  not  have  been  better  to  have  reme- 
died the  inequality?  If  the  state,  instead  of  establishing 
certain  of  the  terms  of  the  labor  contract,  had  made  the 
employee  capable  of  establishing  these  terms  for  himself, 
its  task  would  have  been  much  simplified.  If  the  state  had 
legislated  to  make  equal  the  bargaining  power  of  the  two 
parties,  if  the  state  had  legislated  to  encourage  the  devel- 
opment of  collective  bargaining,  it  would  have  effected  per- 
haps, not  a  panacea,  but  a  much  greater  reform  than  any 
law  so  far  has  effected.  A  really  strong  labor  union  as  a 
means  of  collective  bargaining  would  render  unnecessary 
much  of  the  ever-increasing  bulk  of  social  legislation.  To 
achieve  unionism  should  be  the  first  aim  of  state  activity. 

Experience  sustains  this  conclusion.  The  well-organized 
— I  might  even  say  the  organized — labor  union  asks  little 
of  the  state  except  legal  recognition  and  the  absence  of 
legal  persecution.  It  is  perfectly  reliant  upon  its  own  pow- 
ers. Through  its  control  of  labor  and  its  own  resources,  it 
is  enabled  to  withstand  the  natural  ascendancy  of  the  em- 


152  THE   LABOR  LAW  OF   MARYLAND  [298 

ployer  and  bargain  through  its  trained  agents  for  its  fair 
share  of  the  product.  It  is  within  the  scope  of  the  union's 
power  to  bargain  as  to  hours  of  labor,  wages,  days  of  rest, 
conditions  of  apprenticeship,  etc.  The  trade  union  as  a 
fraternal  organization  can  provide  for  out-of-work  bene- 
fits, sickness  insurance,  old-age  pensions,  and  the  like. 
What  is  more  important,  the  labor  union  can  better  care 
for  the  terms  of  the  employment  of  its  members  through 
its  bargaining  with  the  employer  than  the  state  could 
through  legislative  enactment,  for  the  labor  union  can  bet- 
ter recognize  the  local  and  incidental  variations  of  each 
trade  and  better  provide  for  them  in  its  terms  than  could 
the  state.  Thus  the  English  textile  workers  in  conjunction 
with  the  employers  maintain  expensive  experts  to  arrange 
sliding  scales  of  wages  and  hours  to  conform  to  various 
conditions  and  to  fix  new  terms  when  new  conditions  ar- 
rive.4 And,  furthermore,  with  respect  to  the  benefits,  the 
union  is  able  to  provide  more  efficient  administration  than 
the  state  could  because  of  its  more  intimate  connection  with 
the  recipients  of  the  premiums.  Together  with  the  strength 
and  numbers  of  the  central  and  federal  unions,  these  or- 
ganizations provide  a  much  subdivided  and  minutely  classi- 
fied administrative  device  for  the  amelioration  of  labor 
conditions.  This  must  be  considered  an  additional  argu- 
ment for  the  policy  of  noninterference,  which  indeed 
weighs  very  heavily  in  conjunction  with  individualistic 
reasoning.  In  these  fields  which  have  just  been  discussed 
the  labor  union  can  be  perfectly  efficient,  but  in  order  to 
be  efficient,  it  must  contain  practically  every  worker  in  its 
trade,  perhaps  an  entirely  impracticable  condition. 

The  labor  union,  however,  even  in  its  strongest  condition 
is  not  able  entirely  to  replace  the  state  in  looking  after  the 
welfare  of  the  laborer.  Certain  laws  must  still  be  enacted. 
The  state  must,  of  course,  legislate  with  reference  to  the 
labor  union  itself.  The  union  naturally  must  be  legalized 

4  See  Webb,  Industrial  Democracy,  for  a  description  of  this 
scheme  and  for  an  appreciation  of  its  workings  toward  amicable 
relations  between  labor  and  capital. 


299]        THE  STATE  IN  RELATION  TO  LABOR         1 53 

and,  as  will  be  seen,  aided  in  some  manner  before  it  can 
begin  its  function  as  efficient  competitive  bargainer,  for  the 
common  law,  especially  as  affected  by  early  English  labor 
legislation,  is  not  friendly  to  labor  unions.  In  other  re- 
spects, also,  amendment  of  the  common  law  will  be  neces- 
sary to  conform  this  inelastic  system  to  changing  industrial 
conditions.  The  workmen's  compensation  movement  is  a 
present  instance  of  this  branch  of  state  activity.  The  labor 
union  could  inaugurate  schemes  of  accident  insurance  and 
some  unions  have  done  so;  but  under  the  common  law  of 
master  and  servant  a  scheme  of  accident  insurance  would, 
in  a  great  majority  of  industries,  become  most  expensive. 
The  state  alone  can  abrogate  the  doctrine  of  assumption  of 
risk  and  fellow-servant  negligence  and  ameliorate  or  abro- 
gate the  theory  of  contributory  negligence.  Most  impor- 
tant is  it  that  the  labor  union  should  bargain  for  and  help  to 
regulate  the  conditions  and  environment  of  employment. 
Certain  minor  provisions,  of  course,  the  unions  will  always 
stipulate  for,  but  conditions  of  sanitation,  fire-prevention, 
and  safety  appliances  are  beyond  the  scope  of  their  powers. 
In  the  framing  and  enforcement  of  such  provisions  expert 
knowledge  beyond  the  reach  of  unions  is  necessary;  and, 
moreover,  in  the  fundamentals,  a  uniformity  must  exist 
which  higgling  and  bargaining  from  their  nature  never 
can  procure.  Within  these  three  rubrics,  then,  the  legali- 
zation of  the  union,  the  correction  of  the  common  law, 
and  the  regulation  of  the  conditions  of  labor,  the  activity 
of  the  state  should  be  contained ;  beyond  them  is  the  sphere 
in  which  the  state  should  act  only  in  aid  of  the  union  and 
in  furtherance  of  its  schemes.  In  this  way,  as  I  see  it, 
could  individual  initiative  be  encouraged  and  the  state  care 
best  for  the  general  welfare.  This,  in  other  words,  is  an 
ideal  system  of  state  activity. 

Accepting  provisionally  this  assumption,  the  possibility 
of  which  will  be  later  demonstrated,  that  labor  is  fully 
organized,  that  indeed  each  union  has  a  practical  monopoly 
of  the  workmen  in  its  trade,  the  question  presents  itself: 


I$4  THE  LABOR   LAW   OF   MARYLAND  [300 

Will  the  unions  become  so  strong  when  they  have  once 
been  brought  into  power  that  they  will  not  only  control  the 
capitalists  and  become  the  first  claimants  in  distribution, 
but  that  they  will  set  up  a  kind  of  inverted  autocracy  in 
which  the  union  leaders  represent  their  class  to  the  entire 
emancipation  of  the  capitalists  ?  Such  a  result  seems  some- 
what fantastic,  but  the  recognition  of  its  probability  leads 
to  profitable  speculation. 

In  the  first  place,  even  assuming  that  the  great  propor- 
tion of  laborers  are  unionists,  the  place  of  capital  in  the 
economic  and  social  system  would  still  be  an  important 
one;  and,  unless  communism  followed  unionism — and  this 
does  not  seem  probable  or  even  logical — the  class  of  capi- 
talists would  be  separate  from  and  necessary  to  the  work- 
ingmen.  Moreover,  when  unionism  is  at  its  highest  point, 
from  one-third  to  one-half  of  the  working  population,  farm 
laborers,  professional  men,  and  the  like,  are  engaged  in 
pursuits  in  which  unionization  is  impossible  or  unnecessary. 
And  it  must  be  remembered  that  the  unorganized  portion 
of  the  population  will  still  include  the  professions,  the 
brains  of  the  country.  But,  in  all  this  discussion,  that 
which  must  struggle  for  completion  is  recognized  as  in  full 
bloom  before  any  resistance  or  restriction  is  organized.  Of 
course,  this  is  inconceivable.  With  the  advent  of  fully 
organized  labor,  there  will  develop  organizations  of  em- 
ployers after  the  nature  of  the  present  employers'  associa- 
tions to  combat  the  rising  menace  to  their  profits.  No  gov- 
ernment aid  will  be  needed  to  help  them  into  existence  and 
the  law  will  hardly  antagonize  them  as  union  combatants 
so  long  as  they  restrict  themselves  to  agreements  concern- 
ing labor.  These  employers'  associations  will  also  approach 
to  a  monopoly,  a  monopoly  of  jobs,  and  there  will  be  then 
on  opposite  sides  two  aggressive  organizations,  each  seek- 
ing for  its  members  the  larger  share  in  distribution.  A 
battle  under  those  circumstances  is  inconceivable.  On  be- 
half of  the  consuming  public,  the  state  would  step  in  to 
effect  control  over  those  large  labor  questions  whose  inci- 


3Ol]  THE  STATE  IN  RELATION  TO  LABOR  I  55 

dental  variations  it  had  left  to  the  labor  union.  In  other 
words,  some  form  of  mediation,  arbitration  or  conciliation 
is  necessary. 

It  is  out  of  place  here  to  enter  into  any  detailed  discus- 
sion of  the  modes  of  amicable  settlement  of  labor  disputes. 
The  plan  called  for  here  is  some  kind  of  a  government 
commission  with  the  powers  of  one  of  the  present  minimum 
wage  commissions  to  settle  all  questions  of  terms  of  em- 
ployment which  the  agents  of  the  labor  union  and  employ- 
ers' association  cannot  agree  upon.  The  necessity  of  ap- 
pealing to  this  commission  and  accepting  its  awards  may, 
if  necessary,  be  made  compulsory  and  binding  upon  the 
acceptance  of  government  aid  by  the  unions.  Constitu- 
tional objections  will  be  raised,  but  we  must  sometimes 
remember  that  the  constitutions  are  not  the  last  word  in 
social  legislation  and  social  readjustment. 

There  are,  however,  certain  practical  questions  which 
have  been  slurred  over  in  the  previous  discussion,  but  which 
must  now  be  considered  in  all  their  glaring  baldness.  It  is, 
indeed,  one  of  the  drawbacks  of  philosophizing  and  theoriz- 
ing that  practicalities  always  constrain  one  to  justify  his 
theories.  Perhaps  that  is  why  there  is  such  a  paucity  of 
theories  in  the  world  and  so  many  "practical  men." 

In  the  first  place,  then,  it  has  been  assumed  that,  in  order 
to  guarantee  to  the  state  its  proper  place  in  the  amelioration 
of  social  conditions,  labor  has  become  completely  organized. 
"  The  success  of  a  union  in  enforcing  its  demands  depends 
upon  the  extent  to  which  it  has  control  over  the  labor  sup- 
ply in  its  particular  occupation,  since,  if  an  employer  is 
easily  able  to  fill  the  places  of  those  on  strike,  it  is  evident 
that  the  whole  movement  fails  in  its  purpose."5  It  has 
been  calculated,  however,  that  only  between  five  and  six 
per  cent  of  the  workers  of  the  country  are  organized,  and 
that  few  unions  control  half  the  laborers  in  their  crafts.6 

5Weyforth,  "  Organizability  of  Labor,"  in  Johns  Hopkins  Uni- 
versity Studies,  ser.  xxxv,  no.  2,  p.  146.  Much  of  the  following  has 
been  suggested  by  this  monograph. 

6  Wolman,  Extent  of  Organization  in  the  United  States,  MS. 


156  THE  LABOR  LAW  OF  MARYLAND  [$O2 

These  figures,  however,  exaggerate  the  problem  confront- 
ing us,  though  they  do  suggest  its  magnitude  and,  perhaps, 
the  fancifulness  of  the  project.  One  of  the  greatest  diffi- 
culties in  the  way  of  organizing  laborers  is  the  opposition 
of  the  employers  to  unionization.  This  is  a  natural  phe- 
nomenon of  competition,  but  it  seems  a  passing  one.  Its 
most  destructive  opponents  are  public  opinion  and  the 
growing  consciousness  among  employers  that  it  is  to  the 
benefit  of  each  employer  to  have  all  the  workers  in  his 
trade  organized.  For  only  then  is  the  employer  sure  that 
his  competitor  is  not  undercutting  with  cheap  labor,  and 
his  care  is  to.  obtain  relative,  not  absolute,  cheapness  in  the 
elements  of  his  product.  This  problem,  however,  will  find 
its  own  cure;  legislation  in  its  nature  follows  as  well  as 
develops  public  opinion.  The  country  when  willing  to  ac- 
cept the  scheme  of  legislation  here  set  forth  will  present  a 
concerted  opinion  strong  enough  to  offset  the  opposition  of 
the  employers  to  unionization. 

A  more  serious  problem  confronting  the  organizer  of 
labor,  from  the  point  of  view  of  this  study,  is  the  apathy 
of  the  laborers.  This  manifests  itself  in  two  forms,  in  the 
apathy  of  the  individual  worker  in  an  organized  trade  and 
in  the  apathy  of  a  whole  trade  resulting  from  the  nature 
of  the  trade.  The  indifferent  worker  is  a  problem  for 
modern  unionism  which  the  unions  of  today  are  fast  learn- 
ing to  handle  successfully;  but,  in  the  eyes  of  a  scheme 
which  would  only  succeed  through  a  general  appreciation 
of  the  union  as  the  natural,  fixed  economic  phenomenon 
which  it  seems  to  be,  this  problem  sinks  into  insignificance. 
The  really  serious  difficulty  is  the  apathetic  trade,  the  trade 
which  seems  impervious  to  organization.  The  unskilled, 
floating  workers  because  of  their  great  number  and  the 
aimlessness  of  their  interest,  the  women  in  employment 
because  of  the  transitoriness  of  their  employment  and  be- 
cause they  look  to  marriage  rather  than  wages  as  a  means 
of  livelihood,  and  the  home-workers  because  the  scattered 
condition  of  the  employment  makes  enforcement  of  union 


303]         THE  STATE  IN  RELATION  TO  LABOR 

regulations  well-nigh  impossible  are  the  black  sheep  of  labor 
unionism.  That  a  stimulating  impulse  is  the  necessity  in 
the  case  of  the  unskilled  and  the  women,  that  these  classes 
are  not  impossible,  but  merely  difficult  to  organize,  is  dem- 
onstrated by  the  success  of  such  unions  as  the  stevedores 
and  hodcarriers  and  of  the  New  York  garment  workers' 
protocol.  The  home-workers,  if  the  law  is  content  that 
there  be  home-workers,  seem  conclusively  without  the  field 
of  unionism.  The  isolated  conditions  of  employment,  the 
private  nature  of  their  occupation,  make  impossible  such 
union  regulations  as  an  eight  hour  day,  standard  wages  or 
a  closed  shop.  But  this  is  not  fatal  to  the  argument  that 
the  unions  should  regulate  the  terms  of  employment,  for 
the  same  conditions  would  make  equally  impossible  an  effi- 
cient state  regulation  of  these  terms.  Except  as  to  the 
conditions  of  the  environment  of  employment,  which  under 
any  scheme  of  social  legislation  must  come  under  state  con- 
trol, the  home-workers  are  incapable  of  outside  regulation. 
1  Another  class  of  workers  who  are  not  well  organized  are 
those  who  labor  in  small  one-man  industries.  These  in- 
clude farm  laborers,  domestic  servants,  workmen  in  small 
country  shops,  and  the  workers  in  the  so-called  one-man 
shop.  The  organizing  condition  of  these  employments  is 
analagous  to  that  of  the  home-workers,  but  it  is  not  abso- 
lutely incompatible  with  organization,  as  is  evidenced  by 
unions  of  barbers  and  the  like.  The  labor  problem,  how- 
ever, in  these  industries  is  not  so  acute  as  in  the  larger 
centralized  employments,  for  the  laborer  is  in  intimate  rela- 
tion with  his  employer.  In  fact,  these  occupations  are  quite 
of  the  nature  of  the  early  forms  of  industry  when  no  labor 
legislation  was  enacted,  and  even  today  these  occupations 
are  often  omitted  from  labor  legislation.  Instead  of  en- 
hancing, these  workers  may  be  said  to  mitigate  our  problem. 
The  problem  then  is,  if  it  is  desirable  to  make  the  great- 
est possible  use  of  labor  unions  in  the  amelioration  of  labor 
conditions  and  if  it  is  desirable  to  establish  a  limit  to  state 
intervention  where  the  concerted  action  of  the  workingmen 


158  THE  LABOR  LAW   OF   MARYLAND  [304 

shall  work  out  their  own  salvation, — the  problem  then  is  to 
secure  almost  complete  organization  among  laborers.  Be- 
cause of  the  antipathy  of  the  employers  and  the  apathy  of 
some  laborers,  as  explained,  the  organizability  of  labor 
seems  to  stand  at  a  rather  low  level.  Public  opinion,  it  is 
true,  plays  a  large  part  in  determining  the  level  at  which 
the  labor  barometer  stands,  but  public  opinion  cannot  over- 
come all  the  obstacles  in  the  way  of  labor  organization. 
Active  help  must  be  furnished  from  the  outside.  It  is  here 
that  the  state  may  bargain  for  the  controlling  interest  in  the 
manipulation  of  trade  union  affairs  which  is  necessary  to 
amicable  settlement  of  industrial  disputes.  Two  modes  of 
state  aid  will  illustrate  the  kind  of  help  necessary  and  the 
problems  involved,  but  the  exposition  of  these  two  schemes 
must  not  be  accepted  as  exhaustive  of  the  methods  of  state 
aid. 

The  first  plan  for  state  aid  is  in  the  nature  of  financial 
encouragement.  One  of  the  main  weapons  of  organization 
is  the  beneficial  system  of  trade  union  insurance.  Not  only 
is  this  an  effective  lure  to  the  conservative  workman,  but  it 
is  one  of  the  chief  inducements  to  permanent  organization 
when  the  initial  stimulus  of  a  successful  strike  or  boycott 
has  spent  its  constructive  force.  Two  of  the  most  impor- 
tant of  these  benefits  are  out-of-work  and  sickness  benefits. 
The  state  could  contribute  to  one  of  these  and  make  the 
union  so  much  more  effective  by  its  aid,7  As  a  condition 
of  this  contribution,  the  state  could  stipulate  that  through 

7  The  expense  of  this  scheme  would  not  be  great.  Taking  as  a 
typical  example  of  the  source  of  state  aid,  the  State  of  Maryland,  a 
fair  estimate  would  be  the  addition  of  three  and  one-fifth  cents  to 
the  tax  rate.  This  estimate  is  arrived  at  in  the  following  manner : 
The  working  population  of  Maryland  is  541,164  (Census  of  1910, 
Vol.  V,  p.  in).  Deducting  222,247,  the  number  of  farm-hands,  pro- 
prietors and  professional  men,  etc.,  the  total  number  of  organizable 
workers  at  a  generous  estimate  is  318,917.  The  average  per  capita 
cost  of  out-of-work  benefits  in  two  unions,  the  Cigar  Maker  and 
Typographic,  from  1900  to  1905  was  $3.55  (from  tables  in  Kennedy, 
Beneficiary  Features  of  Trade  Unions,  p.  91).  If  the  State  shouid 
contribute  30  per  cent  of  this  amount,  again  a  most  liberal  estimate, 
the  total  cost  for  Maryland  would  be  $329,647  or  3.2  cents  on  the  tax 
assessment  basis  of  1914. 


305]         THE  STATE  IN  RELATION  TO  LABOR         159 

its  commission  or  board  of  arbitration  or  some  similar 
board,  it  should  have  intimate  control  over  the  affairs  of 
the  union.  This  scheme  would  have  to  meet  the  objections 
against  all  state  insurance  schemes ;  and  it  could  meet  them 
rather  effectively ;  but  none  of  these,  because  of  the  nature 
of  this  discussion,  is  important  to  dwell  upon  except  the 
question  of  constitutionality,  that  bugaboo  of  all  social 
legislation. 

Under  existing  state  constitutions,8  this  method  of  state 
aid  would  be  illegal ;  but  most  state  constitutions  are  easily 
and  often  amended  so  that  the  real  difficulty  lies  in  the 
relatively  staid  Federal  Constitution.  The  "  due  process  of 
law "  clause  interpreted  as  forbidding  state  taxation  for 
private  purposes  and  the  "  equal  protection  of  the  law " 
clause  of  the  Fourteenth  Amendment  as  usual  raise  their 
threatening  forms  in  the  path  of  this  legislation.  In  the 
first  place,  would  such  a  system  of  state  contribution  to 
union  benefits  involve  taxation  for  a  private  purpose? 

The  first  ground  upon  which  this  legislation  would  be 
sought  to  be  upheld  would  naturally  be  as  an  extension  of 
the  proper  state  function  of  poor  relief,  for,  in  taxation 
cases,  the  courts  lend  most  weight  to  the  historical  argu- 
ment. It  might  be  argued  that,  inasmuch  as  the  State  may 
relieve  its  poverty-stricken  citizens,  it  should  be  enabled 
to  grant  aid  as  a  preventative  of  those  conditions.  Now 
the  two  kinds  of  contributions,  of  which  one  is  advocated, 
are  both  directed  against  prime  causes  of  poverty,  the  sick- 
ness or  unemployment  of  the  wage-earner  of  the  family. 
The  argument  is  perfectly  sound  that  an  ounce  of  preven- 
tion is  worth  a  pound  of  cure,  but  the  majority  of  the 
courts  of  the  country  have  refused  to  be  guided  by  this 
proverb.9  State  relief,  it  has  been  generally  held,  can  only 
be  granted  to  those  absolutely  indigent.  At  least  one  court, 

8See,  e.  g.,  the  Maryland  Constitution,  Art.  Ill,  Sec.  34:  "The 
credit  of  the  State  shall  not  in  any  manner  be  given  ...  in  aid  of 
any  individual  association  or  corporation." 

9  See  Goodnow,  Social  Reform  and  the  Constitution,  chap.  7,  and 
cases  there  cited. 


I6O  THE  LABOR   LAW   OF   MARYLAND  [306 

however,  has  taken  the  logical,  if  not  the  historical  and 
legal,  position  just  set  forth  and  has  upheld  a  preventative 
measure;10  but,  except  as  an  entering  wedge,  this  opinion 
lends  little  encouragement  because  of  its  uniqueness. 

Driven  from  this  ground  by  the  conservatism  of  the 
courts,  it  is  more  profitable  to  consider  whether  the  State 
is  not  obtaining  for  itself  by  indirect  means  a  perfectly  valid 
advantage.  "It  is  obvious  that  what  is  a  public  use  fre- 
quently and  largely  depends  upon  the  facts  and  circum- 
stances surrounding  the  particular  subject  matter  in  regard 
to  which  the  character  of  the  use  is  questioned."11  It  is 
useless  to  quote  cases.  The  irreconcilable  differences  of 
the  opinions  makes  it  possible  to  quote  in  favor  of  either 
position.  Let  us  then  appeal  to  reason.  By  making  the 
nominal  expenditure  for  beneficiary  payments,  the  State 
saves  itself  the  cost  of  expensive  commissions  and  experts 
necessary  for  the  efficient  administration  of  this  part  of 
the  labor  law,  saves  its  legislators  endless  trouble  by  ren- 
dering unnecessary  a  great  multitude  of  enactments,  and 
exercises  an  interest  of  utmost  importance  in  maintaining 
amicable  relations  between  employers  and  employees,  in 
preventing  labor  wars.  The  state  takes  this  means  of  legis- 
lating with  respect  to  the  fundamentals  of  the  labor  ques- 
tion instead  of  striving  to  correct  the  deformity  of  modern 
industrial  life  by  attacking  merely  the  symptoms  and  out- 
growths of  the  inequalities  now  existing  between  labor  and 
capital.  The  State,  it  would  seem,  has  a  right  to  legislate 
in  this  manner  and  "it  is  established  by  a  series  of  cases 
that  an  ulterior  public  advantage  may  justify  a  compara- 
tively insignificant  taking  of  private  property  for  what,  in 
its  immediate  purpose,  is  a  private  use."12 

This  line  of  reasoning  also  makes  unnecessary  any  ex- 
tended reference  to  the  "equal  protection  of  the  law" 
clause.  All  unions  and  unionists  will  receive  similar  aid 

"  North  Dakota  v.  Nelson  Co.,  I  N.  D.  88. 

"Fallbrook  Irrigation  District  v.  Bradley,  164  U.  S.  112. 

12  Noble  State  Bank  v.  Haskell,  219  U.  S.  104,  and  cases  cited. 


307]  THE  STATE  IN  RELATION  TO  LABOR  l6l 

from  the  government,  and  everybody  will  be  able  to  secure 
this  aid  by  entering  a  union,  for,  in  fact,  to  secure  complete 
organizations  is  the  prime  motive  of  the  aid.  The  unions, 
through  governmental  insistence,  must  hold  themselves  open 
to  receive  any  worker  having  the  qualifications  of  the  trade ; 
and  the  State  must  stand  ready  to  extend  its  aid  to  all 
unions  coming  into  existence.  All  who  unionize  receive 
government  assistance  and  those  who  refuse  to  organize 
have  themselves  to  blame.  The  discrimination  between 
unionists  and  non-unionists,  in  reality,  amounts  to  very  little, 
and  this  discrimination  is  justified  by  the  end  to  be  attained. 

As  a  second  mode  of  state  encouragement  to  organiza- 
tion, a  scheme  lending  actual  assistance  to  the  establish- 
ment of  a  preferential  union  shop  in  the  several  industries 
is  suggested.  Little  argument  is  necessary  to  prove  that 
if  actual  preference  is  given  to  the  man  bearing  union  cre- 
dentials in  obtaining  the  open  job,  great  advantage  is  given 
to  the  union.  It  would,  perhaps,  be  too  difficult  to  attempt 
to  absolutely  enforce  a  closed  shop  or  even  a  preferential 
shop  by  legal  enactment,  but  any  aid  in  this  direction  would 
be  beneficial,  and  perhaps  sufficiently  beneficial  to  stimulate 
organization  among  the  apathetic  workers,  certainly  bene- 
ficial as  a  weapon  against  the  antipathetic  employers.  It  is 
not  necessary  to  suggest  a  typical  law,  but  it  would  be  in- 
teresting to  consider  the  constitutionality  of  a  law  similar 
to  that  which  has  been  passed  in  several  States  penalizing 
the  discharge  of  a  workingman  because  of  his  membership 
in  a  union  or  penalizing  an  employer  for  insisting  upon  an 
agreement  from  the  worker  not  to  join  a  union  during  his 
employment,  either  of  which  would  be  enforced  only  as  to 
unions  submitting  to  government  intervention  in  their  deal- 
ings with  the  employers. 

At  first  glance,  either  of  these  laws  would  seem  clearly 
unconstitutional  under  decisions  of  the  Supreme  Court  in 
the  Adair18  and  Coppage  cases;14  but  there  is  one  new 

"Adair  v.  United  States,  208  U.  S.  161. 
14  Coppage  v.  Kansas,  236  U.  S.  I. 


1 62  THE   LABOR   LAW  OF   MARYLAND  [308 

feature,  government  control,  introduced  which  will  at  least 
weigh  in  the  direction  of  constitutionality,  and,  moreover, 
it  is  most  deferentially  submitted,  the  decisions  in  these  two 
cases  are  open  to  criticism.  Both  of  the  majority  opinions 
in  these  cases  were  written  by  the  conservative,  if  not  the 
reactionary,  justice  of  the  'bench  and  both  of  them  are  rea- 
soned out  upon  eighteenth  century  notions  of  the  inviola- 
bility of  natural  rights.  The  Court  does  not  take  judicial 
cognizance  of  twentieth  century  conditions  as  affecting 
these  eighteenth  century  rights.  It  lays  aside  as  immaterial 
the  practical  inequality  of  the  employer  and  the  unorgan- 
ized worker  and  sees  no  possibility  of  coercion  in  the  mu- 
tual employment  agreements.  "  But  in  view  of  the  relative 
positions  of  employer  and  employed,"  asks  Justice  Day  in 
"his  dissenting  opinion  in  the  later  case,  "who  is  to  deny 
that  the  stipulation  [not  to  enter  a  union  during  employ- 
ment] here  insisted  upon  and  forbidden  by  law  is  essentially 
coercive?"  It  is  useless  to  attack  at  any  greater  length 
these  decisions;  the  dissenting  opinions  are  stronger  than 
anything  else  which  could  be  written.  The  proposed  laws, 
however,  can  be  held  constitutional  in  spite  of  these  two 
cases.  Not  only  would  the  State  be  attempting  to  aid  the 
unions  by  these  laws,  it  would  be  fulfilling  a  purpose  of  its 
own  in  the  amelioration  of  inequitable  labor  conditions  and 
in  the  amicable  adjustment  of  labor  disputes.  The  unions 
would  take  on  the  nature  of  public  institutions;  and,  as 
the  Court  says  in  the  Goppage  case,  "  if  they  were,  a  differ- 
ent question  would  be  presented  "  than  the  one  there  con- 
sidered. 

These  two  methods  of  state  aid  are,  then,  illustrative  of 
the  kind  of  legislation  needed  to  consummate  the  idealized 
condition  of  affairs  herein  assumed.  To  encourage  indi- 
vidual initiative  and  to  repress  selfishness  in  a  proper  pro- 
portion, so  that  both  the  individual  and  the  community 
may  prosper,  the  State's  first  duty  in  labor  legislation  is  fa 
stimulate  unionization.  Until  complete  unionization  is  at- 
tained, the  State  may  have  to  legislate  in  fields  beyond 


309]        THE  STATE  IN  RELATION  TO  LABOR         163 

those  to  which  this  system  would  limit  it;  and  in  those 
fields  the  previous  chapters  of  this  study  have  sought  to 
lay  down  sound  standards  of  legislation.  When,  however, 
unionization  is  once  complete  and  with  it  have  come  into 
existence  the  employers'  associations,  the  State  will  be  able 
to  leave  most  of  the  terms  of  the  labor  contract  to  the  two 
parties,  itself  intervening  through  the  agency  of  the  gov- 
ernmental commission  only  on  the  rare  occasions  when  the 
public  welfare  seems  at  stake.  The  only  other  care  of  the 
•State  will  be  to  keep  the  unwritten  law  up  to  date  and  to 
legislate  concerning  safety  and  sanitary  conditions.  Per- 
haps this  outline  seems  too  ideal,  but  in  that  it  is  like  all 
logical  philosophies — when  they  become  constructive  they 
necessarily  go  to  extremes  and  extremes  are  not  reason- 
able ;  only  the  mean  is  reasonable  and  that  is  not  logical. 


INDEX 


Accident.     See  Workmen's  Com- 
pensation Law. 
Accident  Fund,  65-66. 
Administration    of     labor     law, 

122  ff. 

Apprentices,  statute  of,  n. 

Arbitration,  compulsory  and  vol- 
untary, 41  ff. ;  publicity  method 
of,  42. 

Assumption  of  risk,  53,  71 

Attachments  and  liens,  n6ff. 

Barnett,  G.  E.,  47  (note). 
Bentham,  Jeremy,  147. 
Black-list,   uses    of,   33-35,   108, 

114. 
Board   for  Mothers'  Relief   for 

Baltimore  City,  119.        • 
Boycott,  22,  25;   secondary,  24, 

25,     29-30;     primary,     39-30; 

distinction     between     primary 

and  secondary,  30-32. 
Brandeis,  L.  D.,  101  (note). 
Brown,  W.  Jethro,  148  (note). 
Bryan,  J.  W.,  20  (note). 
Bureau   of   Industrial   Statistics 

and  Inspection,  87,  98 
Bureau  of  Statistics  and  Infor- 
mation, 43-44,  123,  136. 

Canneries,  102. 

Child  Labor  Law,  99,  101,  126, 

130-131. 

Child  welfare,  117,  119,  132. 
Civil  service  reform,  136  ff. 
Closed  shop,  22,  25 ;  methods  of, 

36-38. 

Colt'hing  Cutters'  Assembly,  25. 
Commission,  proposed,  77  ff. 
Common  law,  relation  to  labor 

law,   10-11;   of  contracts,  37; 

in    relation    to    compensation 

law,  75- 

Commons,  J.  R.,  78  (note),  79. 
Compensation.     See  Workmen's 

Compensation  Law. 
Conciliation,  41-45. 
Conspiracy,  law  of,  19,  20. 


Constitutional  provisions  in 
United  States,  relation  of,  to 
labor  law,  13-14. 

Contract,  freedom  of,  22. 

Contributory  negligence,  53,  71, 

153- 
Cooperative  Insurance  Fund,  46- 

48. 
Course  of  employment,  63  ff. 

Disability,  compensation  for, 

58  ff. 

Discharge  of  employees,  35. 
"Due  process  of  law"  clause,  14, 

153- 

Employers'     Associations,     154, 

155- 

Employers'  Liability  Case,  71. 

Employment,  conditions  of,  76 
ff,;  terms  of,  94 ff.;  prohibi- 
tions of,  96  ff.  See  hours  of 
labor,  sanitation,  fire  protec- 
tion, etc. 

Employment,  in  course  of,  63  ff. 

Employment  agencies,  126. 

Equal  protection,  159,  160. 

Factory    inspection    and    indus- 
trial registration  law,  126  ff. 
Fellow    servant    negligence,    53, 

7i,  153- 
Fire    protection    and    suggested 

measures,  81-85. 
Fourteenth  Amendment',  14,  41 ; 

"  equal  protection  of  the  law  " 

clause  of,  159,  :6o. 
Freund,    Ernst,    48    (note),    55 

(note). 

Goodnow,  F.  J.,  129  (note). 

Harlan,  H.  D.,  74  (note). 
Health,   State  Board  of,   89-90, 

123,  133-135. 

Herkner,  Anna,  83  (note). 
Holmes,  Justice,  14,  36,  71. 
Home-work,  90-93. 


164 


INDEX 


I65 


Hours  of  labor,  for  women  and 
children,  100-103,  I26>  I3a> 
for  men,  103-104. 

Industrial  Accident  Commis- 
sion, State,  65,  67-70,  85,  123, 

T  ?3S.    . 
Injunctions,  30. 

Insurance,  158-161.     See  Work- 
men's Compensation  Law. 
Interlocking  directorates,  no. 

Label,  union,  39-41. 

Labor,    disputes,    settlement   of, 

155. 

Labor,  State  in  relation  to,  145  ff. 

Labor  and  Statistics,  State 
Board  of,  44,  87,  91-92,  123  ff. 

Labor  Day,  121. 

Labor  Department,  need  of 
Maryland  for,  139  ff . 

Labor  law,  definition  of,  9;  dif- 
ferentiation of,  from  common 
law,  10;  character  of  early,  n- 
12,  20. 

Labor  union,  19  ff. 

Laborers,  Statute  of,  n. 

Laissez-faire,  relation  of  doc- 
trine to  labor  law,  11-12,  77, 
147- 

Leiserson,  W.  M.,  126  (note). 

Liability,  employers.  See  Work- 
men's Compensation  Law. 

License  laws,  113  ff.,  115-116. 

Liens,  116. 

Living  wage,  105. 

Lucke  v.  Clothing  Cutters'  As- 
sembly, 25. 

Luman  v.  Kitchens,  in. 

Malice,  22. 

Martin.  W.  A.,  23  (note),  40 
(note). 

Maryland  Court  of  Appeals,  14; 
on  criminal  conspiracy,  20. 

Maryland  Labor  law,  compara- 
tively considered,  16-17;  his- 
torically considered,  19-20 ;  ad- 
ministrative system  of,  122 
ff. ;  suggestions  for  reforms 
in,  136  ff. 

Mechanics'  liens,  n6ff. 

Minimum  wage  law,  104-106. 

Mothers'  pensions,  118. 

My  Maryland  Lodge  v.  Adt,  23- 
24,  28,  30. 


Negligence,  contributory,  53,  71, 
153- 

Occupational  diseases,  64. 

Picketing,  25,  27-29. 

Pickett  v.  Walsh,  26. 

Police  power,  72. 

Public    employment,    terms    of, 

119-120. 
Pure  Food  and  Drugs  Act,  134. 

Relief  fund,  49. 
Restraint  of  trade,  37. 
Risk,  assumption  of,  53,  71. 
Rubinow,  J.  M.,  53  (note). 

Safety   and    sanitary   measures, 

85  ff. 
Sanitary  Inspection  Law,  89-90, 

133-135- 

Sanitation,  86,  129.  See  Health, 
State  Board  of. 

Schaffle,  A.,  149. 

School  attendance,  118. 

Second  Employers'  Liability 
Case,  71. 

Shaffer  v.  Union  Mining  Com- 
pany, no. 

Socialism,  148-149,  150. 

State  Accident  Fund,  65-66. 

State  aid  to  trade  unions,  in- 
surance, 158-161;  preferential 
union  shop,  161 ;  constitution- 
ality of,  161-162. 

State  Board  of   Health,  89-90, 

123,  133-135- 

State  Board  of  Labor  and  Sta- 
tistics, 44,  87,  91-92;  adminis- 
tration and  duties  of,  123  ff. 

State  employment,  H9ff. 

State  Industrial  Accident  Com- 
mission, 65,  67-70,  85,  123, 135. 

State  v.  Potomac  Coal  Com- 
pany, in. 

Statute  of  Apprentices,  Eliza- 
bethan, n. 

Statute  of  Laborers,  n. 

Strike,  object  of,  22  ff.,  38;  sym- 
pathetic, 24;  when  legal  in- 
strument, 24. 

Sunday  Rest  Law,  121. 

Supreme  Court,  on  discharge  of 
union  employees,  35. 

Sympathetic  strike,  24. 


1 66                                                      INDEX  [JI2 

Tenement  law,  90-93.  Wages  of  labor,  104  ff. 

Tort,  law  of,  74.  "  Waiting  period,"  61. 

Trade    union,    development    of  Webb,  Sidney,  152  (note). 

law   of,   in   Maryland,    19-23;  Weyforth,  W.  O.,  155  (note). 

statutes     relating     to,    39-41 ;  Willner  v.  Silverman,  35. 

aims  of,  151-153;  state  aid  to,  Wolman,  Leo,  155  (note). 

158-161.  Women's  ten-hour  law,  102, 126, 

Truck    system,    107  ff.;    history  132. 

of,  in  Maryland,  109  ff.  Workmen's    Compensation   Law 

Typographical    Union,    Interna-  of  Maryland,  history  of,  46  ff. ; 

tional,  41.  compared   with    other   similar 

laws,    56  ff. ;    constitutionality 

Union  label,  30-41.  of,  70  ff.;  effects  on  common 

Union  labor,  19  ff.  law,  74,  125. 
Union  shop,  161. 


THE  AMERICAN  COLONIZATION 
SOCIETY  1817-1840 


ERIES  XXXVII  NO.  3 

JOHNS  HOPKINS  UNIVERSITY  STUDIES 

IN 

HISTORICAL  AND  POLITICAL  SCIENCE 

Under  the  Direction  of  the 

Departments  of  History,  Political  Economy,  and 
Political  Science 


THE  AMERICAN  COLONIZATION 
SOCIETY  1817-1840 


BY 


EARLY   LEE  FOX,  PH.D. 
Professor  of  History  in  Randolph-Macon  College 


BALTIMORE 

THE  JOHNS  HOPKINS  PRESS 
1919 


COPYRIGHT  1919  BY 
THE  JOHNS  HOPKINS  PRESS 


PRESS  OP 

THE  NEW  ERA  PRINTING  COMPANY 
LANCASTER.  PA. 


CONTENTS 

PACK 

PREFACE   vii 

INTRODUCTION   , 9 

CHAPTER     I.  The  Free  Negro  and  the  Slave 13 

CHAPTER  II.  Organization,  Purpose,  Early  Years  ...     46 
CHAPTER  III.  American  Colonization  and  Garrisonian 

Abolition    125 

CHAPTER  IV.  Colonization  and  Emancipation 180 

CHAPTER  V.  Colonization  and  the  African  Slave  Trade  215 


PREFACE 

The  following  study  was  undertaken  at  the  suggestion  of 
Professor  John  H.  Latane,  of  the  Johns  Hopkins  Univer- 
sity. It  is  a  genuine  pleasure  for  me  to  acknowledge  and 
express  my  thanks  for  the  interest  he  has  shown  at  every 
stage  of  the  work.  As  a  result  of  his  instruction,  together 
with  that  of  Professor  J.  M.  Vincent,-  also  of  the  Johns 
Hopkins  University,  I  have  come  to  appreciate,  I  hope,  the 
importance  of  a  critical  evaluation  of  historical  evidence. 
My  thanks  are  also  due  those  connected  with  the  Manu- 
scripts Division  of  the  Library  of  Congress,  where  most  of 
the  research  work  was  done,  and  particularly  to  Mr.  Fitz- 
patrick,  whose  courtesy  I  shall  not  soon  forget.  Rev.  M.  L. 
Fearnow  very  kindly  read  a  portion  of  the  manuscript  and 
suggested  several  changes. 

E.  L.  F. 


VI! 


THE  AMERICAN  COLONIZATION  SOCIETY 
1817-1840 


INTRODUCTION 

It  is  just  a  century  since  a  group  of  men  of  distinguished 
talents  came  together  in  the  city  of  Washington  for  an  inter- 
change of  views  on  the  solution  of  the  negro  problem.  The 
result  was  the  organization  of  the  American  Colonization 
Society.  From  the  time  of  its  inception  the  Society  ap- 
pealed to  men  in  every  walk  of  life  and  from  every  section 
of  the  Union.  The  whole  movement  was  in  response  to  a 
national,  not  a  sectional  sentiment.  From  the  day  of  its 
birth  to  the  day  when,  by  the  proclamation  of  the  president, 
the  slaves  in  the  South  were  set  free,  leaders  of  thought  and 
framers  of  national  policy  looked  to  this  organization  to 
save  them  from  what  Jefferson  had  called  the  fire  bell  in 
the  night. 

Between  the  Missouri  Compromise  and  John  Brown's 
raid  there  were  few  platforms  upon  which  representative 
men  from  New  England,  the  West,  and  the  upper  South 
could  stand  and  discuss  dispassionately  the  negro  problem. 
But  upon  the  platform  of  the  Colonizationists  they  could, 
and  did,  stand.  On  that  platform  stood  Daniel  Webster  of 
Massachusetts  and  William  H.  Crawford  of  Georgia,  Elisha 
Whittlesey  of  Ohio  and  Theodore  Frelinghuysen  of  New 
Jersey.  There  Elijah  Paine,  that  distinguished  farmer, 
jurist,  and  philanthropist  of  Vermont,  could,  in  common 
with  his  neighbor,  Roger  M.  Sherman  of  Connecticut,  talk 
with  the  owner  of  three  hundred  slaves,  William  H.  Fitz- 
hugh  of  Virginia.  There  stood  Francis  Scott  Key,  Charles 
Fenton  Mercer,  John  Marshall,  and  James  Monroe.  There 
the  author  of  the  Olive  Branch  made  common  cause  with 


IO  THE  AMERICAN    COLONIZATION   SOCIETY 

the  editor  of  the  North  American  Review.  There  James 
Madison,  the  father  of  the  Constitution,  was  of  the  same 
mind  as  was  Abraham  Lincoln,  who  stood  as  the  guardian 
of  a  national  spirit  which  that  time  honored  instrument  had 
done  so  much  to  create. 

The  organization  of  the  Methodist  Church  was  rent  in 
twain  over  the  question  of  slavery;  but  Bishop  Beverly 
Waugh,  of  the  Methodist  Episcopal  Church,  was  a  Coloni- 
zationist  in  common  with  Bishop  John  C.  Cranberry,  of  the 
Southern  Methodists;  and  these  made  common  cause  with 
Bishop  Clark  of  Rhode  Island  and  Bishop  Meade  of  Vir- 
ginia, both  of  the  Protestant  Episcopal  Church.  Waldo  of 
Massachusetts,  and  McDonogh  of  New  Orleans,  contrib- 
uted many  thousands  of  dollars  for  the  cause.  Presidents 
McLean  of  Princeton,  Duer  of  Columbia,  Day  of  Yale, 
Everett  and  Sparks  of  Harvard,  were  all  Colonizationists. 
Richard  Rush,  John  Eager  Howard,  Henry  Rutgers,  John 
Taylor  of  Caroline,  General  George  Mason,  General  Walter 
Jones,  Robert  Ralston,  Benjamin  F.  Butler  of  New  York, 
John  Tyler,  Henry  A.  Wise,  J.  J.  Crittenden,  Abel  P.  Up- 
shur,  M.  C.  Perry,  and  Levi  Lincoln,  men  who  thought  dif- 
ferently along  many  lines,  all  supported  the  colonization 
movement. 

The  decade,  1830-1840,  witnessed  the  development  of 
large  areas  of  the  Southwest,  and  with  the  economic  change 
came  a  fundamental  change  in  the  point  of  view  of  the 
South  toward  slavery.  Professor  Dew's  contribution  in 
the  "  Pro-Slavery  Argument "  is  indicative  of  a  lamentable 
change  that  was  coming  over  the  mind  and  conscience  of  the 
South.  If  ever,  during  the  nineteenth  century,  conditions 
in  the  United  States  called  for  the  leadership  of  men  of 
foresight  and  moderation  to  set  forth  convincingly  the  evils 
of  the  system  that  was  getting  its  hold  on  the  South,  that 
time  was  1831  and  the  ten  years  following.  The  Coloniza- 
tionists, both  Northern  and  Southern,  attempted  to  provide 
just  such  men  and  just  such  leadership.  It  was  with  the 
secret  cooperation  of  the  American  Colonization  Society 


323]  INTRODUCTION  II 

that  Jesse  Burton  Harrison,  a  native  of  Virginia  who  was 
then  living  in  New  Orleans,  contributed  to  the  American 
Quarterly  Review  his  "Review  of  the  Slave  Question," 
which  was  intended  to  counteract  the  undoubtedly  great  in- 
fluence of  Professor  Dew's  argument.  Harrison  appealed 
to  the  Southern  States,  and  particularly  Virginia,  to  throw 
off  that  greatest  hindrance  to  economic  development.  What 
would  have  been  the  result  if  such  a  campaign  as  that  begun 
by  Harrison  had  been  allowed  to  go  on  unobstructed  for  a 
decade  or  a  generation  it  is  not  possible  to  say ;  but  that  this 
was  precisely  an  important  part  of  the  program  of  the  Colo- 
nizationists  will  appear  in  the  pages  which  follow. 

To  look  upon  the  American  Colonization  Society  as  an 
organization  whose  success  is  to  be  measured  solely  by  the 
number  of  shiploads  of  negroes  taken  to  Africa  is  to  mis- 
understand the  whole  movement.  Any  adequate  estimate 
of  the  work  of  Colonizationists  must  take  into  account  the 
effect  of  their  program  upon  the  preservation  of  national 
unity.  And  yet,  measured  concretely,  the  Colonization  So- 
ciety was  a  potent  factor  in  securing  the  emancipation  of 
slaves,  thousands  of  them,  and  would  have  secured  the  lib- 
eration of  thousands  more,  had  not  the  rapid  expansion  of 
the  Southwest,  the  consequent  increased  demand  for  slaves, 
and  the  counteracting  influences  of  hostile  propagandists 
brought  about  the  enforcement  of  hitherto  laxly  enforced 
laws  and  the  enactment  of  more  stringent  laws  prohibiting 
emancipations. 

The  influence  of  the  Society  in  the  suppression  of  the 
slave  trade  has,  it  seems,  been  entirely  overlooked ;  and  yet, 
there  was  a  time  in  its  history  when  it  probably  saved  from 
transportation  into  slavery  no  fewer  than  twenty  thousand 
native  Africans  a  year. 

The  limitations  of  both  time  and  space  that  are  neces- 
sarily imposed  upon  one  who  undertakes  to  make  a  study 
of  this  character  have  made  it  impracticable  to  present  here 
a  complete  history  of  the  Colonization  Society.  That  his- 
tory covers  one  hundred  years;  for  the  Society  is  still  in 


12  THE  AMERICAN   COLONIZATION  SOCIETY  [324 

existence,  although,  since  the  close  of  the  Civil  War,  its  in- 
fluence has  been  considerably  limited  and  it  now  undertakes 
but  a  very  small  part  of  what  it  once  undertook.  It  has 
been  impracticable  here  to  extend  the  study  even  to  the 
opening  of  the  Civil  War  except  in  the  influence  of  the  So- 
ciety upon  the  slave  trade  and  upon  emancipations  and 
manumissions.  The  period  covered  is  limited  to  the  years 
1817  to  1840.  No  one  who  is  even  tolerably  acquainted 
with  the  Society's  history  after  its  reorganization  in  1839, 
when  it  came  under  the  control  of  the  North  Middle  and 
New  England  States,  can  have  the  slightest  well-founded 
suspicion  that  thereafter  it  pursued  a  proslavery  policy.  It 
has  been  the  chief  aim  of  the  writer  to  set  forth  unequivo- 
cally its  aims  and  purposes  prior  to  that  time.  The  years 
1839  and  1840  were  years  of  severe  strain  upon  the  So- 
ciety, and  some  of  the  most  persistent  of  its  leaders  were 
in  low  spirits  during  that  time.  This  will  appear  at  the 
close  of  the  second  chapter.  But  this  by  no  means  signifies 
that  there  were  not  brighter  days  ahead.  Indeed,  the  So- 
ciety's resources  grew  rapidly  from  1840  to  the  very  begin- 
ning of  the  Civil  War.  From  1817  to  1839  Colonizationists 
looked  upon  their  work  chiefly  from  the  point  of  view  of 
its  effect  upon  the  solution  of  the  negro  problem  in  the 
United  States ;  after  1840  they  looked  upon  it  chiefly  from 
the  point  of  view  of  its  effect  in  building  upon  the  coast  of 
Africa  a  model  negro  republic.  The  object,  in  this  study, 
has  been  to  set  forth  fully  and  completely  this  first  period 
of  its  history. 


CHAPTER  I 
THE  FREE  NEGRO  AND  THE  SLAVE 

As  late  as  1825  New  England  had  not  forgotten  that  she 
had  had  a  part  in  the  introduction  of  negro  slaves  into  the 
Southern  States.  In  that  year  Daniel  Dana,  addressing  the 
New  Hampshire  Auxiliary  Colonization  Society,  said : 

Let  us  not  imagine,  for  a  moment,  that  we  in  this  Northern  clime, 
are  exempt  from  that  enormous  guilt,  connected  with  slavery,  and 
the  slave-trade,  which  we  are  so  ready  to  appropriate  to  our  brethren 
in  distant  States.  We  have  no  right  thus  to  wash  our  hands.  From 
New  England  have  gone  the  ships  and  the  sailors  that  have  been  pol- 
luted with  this  inhuman  traffic.  In  New  England  are  the  forges 
which  have  framed  fetters  and  manacles  for  the  limbs  of  unoffend- 
ing Africans.  The  iron  of  New  England  has  pierced  their  anguished 
souls.  In  New  England  are  found  the  over-grown  fortunes,  the 
proud  palaces  which  have  been  reared  up  from  the  blood  and  suffer- 
ings of  these  unhappy  men.  The  guilt  is  strictly  national.  .  .  .  Na- 
tional, then,  let  the  expiation  be.  Let  us  raise  up  the  humbled  chil- 
dren of  Africa  from  their  dust.  .  .  .  Let  us  send  them  back  to  their 
native  land.1 

Four  years  later  a  clergyman  from  Maine,  who  hailed  the 
organization  of  the  American  Colonization  Society  as  the 
most  promising  means  of  ridding  the  land  of  slavery,  but 
whose  faith  in  its  efforts  was  shaken  on  his  hearing  that 
plantation  owners  who  had  not  set  free  their  slaves  were 
prominent  in  the  movement,  made  the  following  confession : 

With  many  others  of  the  Northern  people,  I  have  long  enter- 
tained erroneous  views.  I  have  supposed  that  slavery  was  an  evil 
confined  merely  to  the  slave-holder  himself,  and  that  he  might  and 
ought  immediately  to  manumit  his  slaves.  But  I  am  convinced  that 
slavery  is  a  National  sin !  that  we,  who  are  so  far  removed  from  the 
scene  of  its  abominations,  partake  of  its  guilt  1  that  it  is  an  evil 
which  is  entailed  upon  the  present  generation  of  slave-holders,  which 
they  must  suffer,  whether  they  will  or  not;  and  therefore  the  North 
should  aid  the  South,  in  the  expense  of  emancipating  and  transport- 
ing their  slaves  back  to  the  land  of  their  fathers.8 

1  African  Repository,  vol.  i,  p.  146. 

2  Ibid.,  voL  v,  pp.  78-80. 

13 


14  THE  AMERICAN    COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [326 

Professor  Silliman,  of  Yale,  called  attention  to  the  fact 
that  had  New  England,  New  York,  New  Jersey,  and  Penn- 
sylvania been  cotton  producing  States,  the  slave  system 
would  have  been  fastened  on  them  "to  the  full  extent  of 
profitable  employment,"  and  he  added: 

Neither  can  it  be  denied  that  the  slave  trade,  for  the  supply  of 
.the  South,  was  carried  on  by  too  many  persons  in  the  North.  .  .  . 

Slavery  is  now  generally  acknowledged,  in  this  country,  txTBe  an 
enormous  evil.  .  .  .  costly  to  the  proprietor,  ...  a  source  of  increas- 
ing domestic  danger;  an  insult  to  the  purity  of  our  religion  and  an 
outrage  on  the  Majesty  of  Heaven.  This  language  is  not  stronger 
than  that  which  lately  resounded  in  the  Capital  of  Virginia.  This  is 
not  the  proper  occasion  to  discuss,  the  project  of  the  entire  and  im- 
mediate abolition  of  slavery;  it  is  enough  that  it  is,  at  present,  im- 
practicable; nor  will  we  take  upon  us,  to  reprehend  with  severity, 
the  intemperate,  uncourteous  and  unchristian  language  with  which 
the  friends  of  Colonization  are  from  certain  [abolition]  quarters, 
assailed  through  the  press.  .  .  .  Should  their  attempt  fail,  through 
the  unfair  and  unjust  opposition  of  its  enemies,  the  latter  will  have 
much  to  answer  for,  to  Africa  itself,  and  to  the  African  race  in  this 
country,  and  to  the  world.3 

>A/  The  attitude  of  the  upper^  South^  toward  the  question  of 
(#\negro  slavery  went  through  three  distinct  and  important 
phases  from  colonial  times  to  the  beginning  of  the  Civil 
War.  The  period  from  the  beginning  to  the  close  of  the 
eighteenth  century  may  be  considered  approximately  the 
period  of  the  first  phase,  when  the  colonies  sought  from  the 
king  relief  from  the  alarming  growth  of  the  slave  system. 
Of  this  period,  suffice  it  here  to  say  that  the  single  colony 
of  Virginia  passed  twenty-three  acts  whose  object  was  the 
suppression  of  the  evils  of  slavery.  All  these  came  to 
naught  as  the  result  of  the  royal  veto.4  The  third  period 
extended  from  1835  or  1840  to  the  beginning  of  the  Civil 
War.  This  was  the  period  during  which  the  South  was 
definitely  and  frankly  set  on  the  continuation  of  the  slave 
system.  It  was  the  period  between  the  years  1800,  and  par- 
ticularly between  1815,  and  1835  or  1840,  that  claims  special 
attention  in  this  study.  If  during  the  first  period  the  evils 
were  clearly  anticipated  and  the  system  called  forth  pro- 
tests, if  during  the  last  period  the  visions  of  Southerners 


8  Ibid.,  vol.  viii,  pp.  161-187. 
4  Ibid.,  1828,  pp.  172-179. 


327]  THE   FREE    NEGRO  AND   THE   SLAVE  I  5 

were  blurred  as  a  result  of  a  supposed  economic  self-interest 
and  resentment  at  the  course  of  radical  Abolitionists,  during., 
the  middle  period  slavery  was  looked  upon  by  leaders  of  V" 
thought  in  the  South  and  in  the  North  as  one  of  the  great 
national  problems  that  pressed  for  a  solution.  The  Ameri- 
can Colonization  Society  undoubtedly  came  into  being  as  a 
result  of  this  point  of  view.  The  men  who  are  to  be  con- 
sidered its  founders  recognized  in  both  the  free  negro  and 
the  slave  a  momentous  problem,  and  the  aim  of  Coloniza- 
tionists  was  to  find  a  satisfactory  solution  of  it.  The  aim 
of  the  writer  is  to  present  here  fairly  and  fully  the  nature 
of  that  problem. 

South  Carolina  and  Georgia,  and  a  large  part  of  Alabama, 
never  engaged  with  enthusiasm  in  the  work  of  Colonization. 
The  Southwestern  States  were  but  recently  admitted  into 
the  Union.  It  was  that  group  of  States  stretching  from, 
and  including,  New  York  at  the  North,  to,  and  including, 
North  Carolina  at  the  South,  and  from  the  Atlantic  sea- 
board to  the  western  limit  of  Kentucky,  that  seemed  to  un- 
derstand fully  the  gravity  of  that  problem ;  yet  throughout 
the  first  thirty  years  of  the  nineteenth  century  the  evils  of 
slavery  were  admitted  by  well  nigh  every  State  in  the  Union. 

Then,  why  did  not  the  slaveholding  States  at  this  time 
abolish  slavery  ?  Because  they  did  not  know  how ;  because 
the  abolition  of  slavery  was  the  greatest  problem  the  South 
had  ever  been  called  on  to  face ;  because  no  man  had  sug- 
gested a  plan  that  seemed  capable  of  execution.  As  late  as 
1828,  J.  B.  Harrison,  of  Virginia,  a  man  who  had  traveled 
a  great  deal  in  his  State  and  who  spoke  with  authority,  de- 
clared :  "  Almost  all  masters  in  Virginia  assent  to  the  propo- 
sition, that  when  the  slaves  can  be  liberated  without  danger 
to  ourselves,  and  to  their  own  advantage,  it  ought  to  be 
done."5 

As  early  as  1804,  Dr.  William  Thornton,  the  versatile  and 
distinguished  friend  of  Washington,  wrote:  "I  condemn 
not,  but  feel  for  the  situation  of  the  possessors  of  slaves. 

s  Ibid.,  1828,  p.  305. 


1 6  THE  AMERICAN    COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [328 

It  is  a  misery  entailed  on  them  by  those  who  did  not  deeply 
study  the  laws  of  humanity,  and  who  depended  too  implicitly 
on  laws  grounded  in  impolicy  and  excluding  justice/'6  And 
Gerrit  Smith,  who  later  became  an  ardent  Abolitionist,  said, 
in  1828:  "I  am  certainly  far  from  reproaching  our  slave- 
holders with  the  peculiar  relation  in  which  they  stand  to- 
wards some  of  their  hapless  fellow  creatures.  It  is  not  the 
fault  of  most  of  those  slaveholders.  Most  of  them  were 
born  to  that  relation.  Many  of  them  sincerely  deplore  this 
part  of  their  inheritance."7  President  Nott,  of  Union  Col- 
lege, said,  in  1829 :  "  Our  Brethren  of  the  South,  have  the 
sympathies,  the  same  moral  sentiments,  the  same  love  of 
liberty  as  ourselves.  By  them,  as  by  us,  slavery  is  felt  to 
be  an  evil,  a  hindrance  to  our  prosperity,  and  a  blot  upon 
our  character.  But  it  was  in  being  when  they  were  born 
and  has  been  forced  upon  them  by  a  previous  generation."8 
In  1827  C.  F.  Mercer  reported  for  a  committee  of  the  House 
of  Representatives,  in  reply  to  memorials  of  the  friends  of 
Colonization : 

In  many  States  .  .  .  [the]  total  number  [of  slaves]  was,  as  it  still 
continues  to  be,  so  great,  that  universal  or  general  emancipation 
could  not  be  hazarded,  without  endangering  a  convulsion  fatal  to 
the  peace  of  society.  .  .  .  Nowhere  in  America  .  .  .  has  emancipa- 
tion elevated  the  colored  race  to  perfect  equality  with  the  white ;  and 
in  many  States  the  disparity  is  so  great  that  it  may  be  questioned 
whether  the  condition  of  the  slave,  while  protected  by  his  master, 
however  degraded  in  itself,  is  not  preferable  to  that  of  the  free 
negro.  [And  yet,  even  in  these  States,]  the  principle  of  voluntary 
emancipation  has  operated  to  a  much  greater  extent  than  the  laws 
themselves,  or  the  principle  of  coercion  upon  the  master  has  ever 
done,  even  among  those  States  who  had  no  danger  whatever  to  ap- 
prehend from  the  speedy  and  universal  extension  of  human  liberty.9 

In  a  letter  received  from  a  gentleman  in  Massachusetts 
by  the  secretary  of  the  Colonization  Society  in  1826,  we  find 
this  statement: 

The  late,  and  more  frequent  emancipations  in  the  middle  and 
southern  States,  is  producing  a  very  happy  influence  on  the  public 

6  William  Thornton  Papers,  MS.,  vol.  xiv,  "Letter  to  a  Friend." 
1804. 

7  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  G.  Smith  to  R. 
R.  Gurley,  Nov.  17,  1828. 

8  African  Repository,  vol.  v,  pp.  277-278. 

6  27th  Cong.,  3d  sess.,  House  Report  no.  283,  pp.  408-414. 


329]  THE   FREE   NEGRO  AND  THE  SLAVE  I/ 

mind,  generally  in  this  part  of  the  country.  They  give  a  spring  to 
public  sentiment,  and  they  teach  this  great  lesson,  which  we  north- 
erners are  beginning  to  understand,  that  many  slaveholders  retain 
their  slaves  not  because  they  love  slavery;  but  because  they  cannot 
better  the  condition  of  their  slaves  by  emancipating  them.  .  .  .  The 
south  and  the  north,  I  am  fully  persuaded,  after  having  recently 
traveled  thro'  nearly  all  the  states  of  this  happy  Union,  are  approach- 
ing every  day  towards  the  same  views  in  reference  to  this  whole  sub- 
ject of  our  African  population,  both  the  bond  and  the  free.  .  .  .  The 
influence  of  your  Society  on  public  sentiment  is  the  main  thing.  .  .  .10 

The  following  comment  appeared  in  the  New  York  Tract 
Magazine : 

What  is  the  condition  and  character  of  those  who  are  emancipated? 
...  In  general  black  people  gain  little,  in  many  instances  they  are 
great  losers,  by  emancipation.  Law  may  relieve  them  from  slavery, 
but  laws  cannot  change  their  colour.11 

In  1818,  the  General  Assembly  of  the  Presbyterian  Church, 
at  its  meeting  in  Philadelphia,  declared : 

We  do,  indeed,  tenderly  sympathize  with  those  portions  of  pur 
church  and  our  country,  where  the  evil  of  slavery  has  been  entailed 
upon  them ;  where  a  great,  and  the  most  virtuous  part  of  the  com- 
munity abhor  slavery,  and  wish  its  extermination,  as  sincerely  as 
any  other;  but  where  the  number  of  slaves,  their  ignorance,  and 
their  vicious  habits  generally,  render  an  immediate  and  universal 
emancipation  inconsistent,  alike,  with  the  safety  and  happiness  of 
the  master  and  the  slave.12 

A  most  valuable  contribution  to  the  discussion  of  this 
whole  subject  is  to  be  found  in  a  letter  from  Francis  Scott 
Key  to  Benjamin  Tappan,  in  1838.  At  a  general  confer- 
ence of  Congregational  Churches  the  question  of  slavery  was 
up  for  discussion.  It  was  proposed  to  appoint  a  commit- 
tee to  correspond  with  prominent  Southerners,  in  an  effort 
to  find  out  the  true  sentiments  of  that  section  on  the  subject 
of  slavery.  Tappan  put  to  Key  a  number  of  definite  ques- 
tions. Key  prefaced  his  reply  by  saying  that  he  had  been 
born  and  reared  in  Maryland,  a  slaveholding  State,  but  "  No 
Northern  man  began  the  world  with  more  enthusiasm 
against  slavery  than  I  did.  For  forty  years  and  upwards,  I 
have  felt  the  greatest  desire  to  see  Maryland  become  a  free 

10  African  Repository,  vol.  ii,  pp.  121-122. 

11  Ibid.,  vol.  i,  pp.  91-92. 

12  Ibid.,  vol.  i,  pp.  272-276. 


18  THE  AMERICAN   COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [330 

State,  and  the  strongest  conviction  that  she  could  become 
so."  For  he  believed  that  "no  slave  State  adjacent  to  a 
free  State  can  continue  so,"  the  superiority  of  free,  over 
slave,  labor  being  so  clearly  demonstrated,  and  the  power  of 
public  sentiment  being  so  strong  that  gradual  emancipation 
would  always  result.  He  continues : 

I  have  emancipated  seven  of  my  slaves.  They  have  done  pretty 
well,  and  six  of  them,  now  alive,  are  supporting  themselves  com- 
fortably and  creditably.  Yet  I  cannot  but  see  that  this  is  all  they 
are  doing  now;  and,  when  age  and  infirmity  come  upon  them,  they 
will  probably  suffer.  It  is  to  be  observed,  also,  that  these  were 
selected  individuals,  who  were,  with  two  exceptions,  brought  up  with 
a  view  to  their  being  so  disposed  of,  and  were  made  to  undergo  a 
probation  of  a  few  years  in  favorable  situations,  and,  when  emanci- 
pated, were  far  better  fitted  for  the  duties  and  trials  of  their  new 
condition  than  the  general  mass  of  slaves.  Yet  I  am  still  a  slave- 
holder, and  could  not,  without  the  greatest  inhumanity,  be  otherwise. 
I  own,  for  instance,  an  old  slave,  who  has  done  no  work  for  me  for 
years.  I  pay  his  board  and  other  expenses,  and  cannot  believe  that 
I  sin  in  doing  so. 

The  laws  of  Maryland  contain  provisions  of  various  kinds,  under 
which  slaves,  in  certain  circumstances,  are  entitled  to  petition  the 
courts  for  their  freedom.  As  a  lawyer,  I  always  undertook  these 
cases  with  peculiar  zeal,  and  have  been  thus  instrumental  in  liber- 
ating several  large  families  and  many  individuals.  I  cannot  remem- 
ber more  than  two  instances,  out  of  this  large  number,  in  which  it 
did  not  appear  that  the  freedom  I  so  earnestly  sought  for  them  was 
their  ruin.  It  has  been  so  with  a  very  large  proportion  of  all  others 
I  have  known  emancipated. 

Tappan's  first  question  was :  "  Does  the  opinion  generally 
prevail  among  the  ministers  and  members  of  southern 
churches  that  slaveholding  as  practised  in  this  country,  is 
sanctioned  by  the  Word  of  God?  If  this  is  not  their  opin- 
ion, how  do  they  justify  themselves  in  holding  slaves?" 
Key's  reply  was  that  he  thought  that  the  Bible  neither  sanc- 
tioned slaveholding,  under  all  circumstances,  nor  prohibited 
slaveholding,  under  all  circumstances.  The  golden  rule 
should  be  applied  in  each  particular  case.  He  continued : 

Hundreds  and  thousands  of  Christians,  showing  in  their  whole  life, 
undoubted  evidences  of  the  faith  which  they  profess,  have  so  applied 
this  rule  to  their  consciences,  and  so  come  to  this  conclusion.  Their 
brethren  at  the  North,  knowing  nothing  of  the  peculiar  circum- 
stances under  which  they  have  acted,  nor  of  the  care  and  faithful- 
ness with  which  they  have  inquired  and  decided,  call  upon  them  to 
justify  themselves  for  violating  the  sanctions  of  God's  Word. 


THE   FREE    NEGRO   AND   THE   SLAVE  19 

Key  pointed  out  conditions  under  which  slaveholding  was 
in  his  opinion  a  duty.  For  instance,  a  man  inherits,  through 
no  fault  of  his  own,  an  old  slave,  too  old  to  work  or  to  care 
for  himself.  So  also,  in  the  case  of  a  slave  by  nature  so 
indolent  and  intemperate  that  without  restraint  he  would  be 
wretched  himself  and  a  burden  to  others.  So,  too,  in  the 
case  of  a  slave  purchased  in  order  that  he  might  not  be  sold 
in  one  of  the  distant  States,  and  thus  separated  from  a  wife 
and  family  who  lived  on  a  neighboring  plantation;  or,  in 
the  case  of  the  purchase  by  one  man  of  the  slave  of  another, 
in  order  to  save  the  slave  from  cruel  and  unjust  treatment. 

Another  question  put  to  Key  was:  "Do  professors  of 
religion  forfeit  their  Christian  character  by  buying  and  sell- 
ing slaves,  as  they  may  find  it  convenient?  or  do  they  sub- 
ject themselves  to  censure  and  discipline  by  any  immorality 
or  ill  treatment  of  which  they  might  be  guilty  towards  their 
slaves  ?  "  The  reply  was : 

The  persons  among  us  who  buy  and  sell  slaves  for  profit  are  never, 
as  I  have  ever  heard  or  believe,  professors  of  religion.  Such  con- 
duct, or  any  immorality  or  ill  treatment  towards  their  slaves,  would 
forfeit  their  Christian  character  and  privileges,  if  their  minister  did 
his  duty.  And  nothing  more  disgraces  a  man,  in  general  estimation, 
than  to  be  guilty  of  any  immorality  or  ill  treatment  towards  his 
slaves.13 

DeTocqueville,  that  keen  observer  of  American  institu- 
tions, expressed  sentiments  of  great  value  to  those  who  had 
ears  to  hear.  He  demonstrated  beyond  a  doubt,  that  the 
abolition  of  slavery  in  the  South  was  a  far  different  prob- 
lem from,  and  a  far  graver  problem  than,  its  abolition  in 
the  North.  This  was  true  (i)  because  the  climate  of  the 
South  was  far  more  favorable  to  slave  labor  than  the  cli- 
-mate  of  the  North ;  (2)  because  of  the  nature  of  the  North- 
ern and  of  the  Southern  crops,  the  former  requiring  atten- 
tion only  at  intervals,  the  latter  requiring  almost  constant 
attention;  (3)  because  of  the  tendency  of  slavery  to  move 
toward  the  South. 

He  pointed  out  the  fact  that  in  1830  there  was  in  Maine 
13  Ibid.,  vol.  xv,  pp.  113-125. 


2O  THE  AMERICAN   COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [332 

only  one  negro  for  every  three  hundred  of  the  whites;  in 
Massachusetts.  one-Jiegro-ior  every  one  hundred;  in  Vir- 
ginia forty-two  for  every  one  hundred;  in  South  Carolina 
fifty-five  for  every  one  hundred.^  And  his  conclusion  was 
that  "  the  most  Southern  States  of  the  Union  cannot  abolish 
slavery  without  incurring  very  great  danger,  which  the 
North  had  no  reason  to  apprehend  when  it  emancipated  its 
black  populationX'  "The  Northern  States  had  nothing  to 
fear  from  the  contrast,  because  in  them  the  blacks  were  few 
in  number,  and  the  white  population  was  very  considerable. 
But  if  this  faint  dawn  of  freedom  were  to  show  two  mil- 
lions of  men  their  true  position,  the  oppressors  would  have 
reason  to  tremble."  He  disclaimed  any  sympathy  with  the 
principle  of  negro  slavery,  but  said : 

I  am  obliged  to  confess  that  I  do  not  regard  the  abolition  of  slavery 
as  a  means  of  warding  off  the  [to  him,  inevitable]  struggle  of  the 
two  races  in  the  United  States.  The  negroes  may  long  remain  slaves 
without  complaining;  but  if  they  are  once  raised  to  the  level  of  free 
men,  they  will  soon  revolt  at  being  deprived  of  all  civil  rights;  and 
as  they  cannot  become  the  equals  of  the  whites,  they  will  speedily 
declare  themselves  as  enemies.  In  the  North  everything  contributed 
to  the  emancipation  of  the  slaves ;  and  slavery  was  abolished,  with- 
out placing  the  free  negroes  in  a  position  which  could  become  for- 
midable, since  their  number  was  too  small  for  them  to  claim  the 
exercise  of  their  rights.  But  such  is  not  the  case  in  the  South.  The 
question  of  slavery  was  a  question  of  commerce  and  manufacture 
for  the  slave-owners  in  the  North;  for  those  of  the  South,  it  is  a 
question  of  life  and  death. 

When  I  contemplate  the  condition  of  the  South,  I  can  only  dis- 
cover two  alternatives  which  may  be  adopted  by  the  white  inhabi- 
tants of  those  States ;  viz.,  either  to  emancipate  the  negroes,  and  to 
intermingle  with  them ;  or,  remaining  isolated  from  them,  to  keep 
them  in  a  state  of  slavery  as  long  as  possible.  All  intermediate 
measures  seem  to  me  likely  to  terminate,  and  that  shortly,  in  the 
most  horrible  of  civil  wars,  and  perhaps  in  the  extirpation  of  one 
or  other  of  the  two  races.14 

In  a  memorial  from  the  Colonization  Society  to  Congress 
in  1819,  the  following  sentiment  is  expressed : 

If  one  of  these  consequences  [that  is,  a  consequence  of  Coloniza- 
tion] shall  be  the  gradual  and  almost  imperceptible  removal  of  a 
national  evil,  which  all  unite  in  lamenting,  and  for  which,  with  the 
most  intense,  but  hitherto  hopeless,  anxiety  the  patriots  and  states- 
men of  our  country  have  laboured  to  discover  a  remedy,  who  can 

14  DeTocqueville,  Democracy  in  America,  D.  Appleton  and  Com- 
pany, ed.  of  1904,  vol.  i,  pp.  383-404- 


333]  THE  FREE   NEGRO  AND  THE  SLAVE  21 

doubt,  that  of  all  the  things  we  may  be  permitted  to  bequeath  to  our 
descendants,  this  will  receive  the  richest  tribute  of  their  thanks  and 
veneration?  Your  memorialists  cannot  believe  that  such  an  evil, 
universally  acknowledged  and  deprecated,  has  been  irremovably  fixed 
upon  us.  Some  way  will  always  be  opened  by  Providence,  by  which 
a  people,  desirous  of  acting  justly  and  benevolently,  may  be  led  to 
the  attainment  of  a  meritorious  object.15 

Dr.  William  Thornton  had  pointed  out  clearly  in  1804  the 
seriousness  of  the  problem  of  the  abolition  of  slavery  in  the 
South  as  compared  with  its  abolition  in  the  North.  At  that 
time  he  said  that,  in  the  North,  the  comparatively  few  slaves 
were  so  distributed  among  the  population  that  a  general 
emancipation  fell  but  lightly  upon  each  owner ;  whereas,  in 
the  South,  "  it  would  perhaps  be  requiring  too  much  from 
humanity,  to  expect  those  who  hold  slaves  to  emancipate 
them,  and  thus  reduce  their  own  families  from  affluence  to 
absolute  miser»*r  And  there  is  frequently  no  alternative." 
He  deprecates  the  evils  of  slavery,  but  "  it.has  been  not  only 
a  query  with  others,  but  with  myself,  whether  this  partial 
good  does  not  increase  the  general  evil.  .  .  .  Evil  therefore 
rests  on  evil  till  a  mountain  rises  whose  summit  is  shadowed 
by  a  cloud  of  sin."16  And  many  years  later  Henry  Clay,  in 
a  speech  on  the  subject  of  Abolition  petitions,  made  in  the 
United  States  Senate,  February  7,  1839,  estimated  the  value 
of  property  in  slaves,  in  the  South,  at  $1,200,000,000 — owned 
by  persons  of  all  classes,  those  who  could  afford  to  emanci- 
pate their  slaves  and  very  many  who  could  not.  Slave  prop- 
erty, he  said,  "is  the  subject  of  mortgages,  deeds  of  trust, 
and  family  settlements.  It  has  been  made  the  basis  of  nu- 
merous debts  contracted  upon  its  faith,  and  is  the  sole  re- 
liance, in  many  instances,  of  creditors  witnin  and  without 
the  slave  States,  for  the  payments  of  debt  due  to  them."17 

It  is  also  to  be  observed  that  those  proprietors  who  were 
most  anxious  to  emancipate  their  slaves  were  the  very  ones 
from  whom  the  slaves  received  the  most  consideration. 
Scores  of  instances  could  be  noted  of  the  proffer  of  their 

15  Origin,  Constitution,  and  Proceedings,  MS.,  American  Coloni- 
zation Society,  vol.  i,  pp.  127-128. 

16  Thornton  Papers. 

17  African  Repository,  vol.  xv,  pp.  150-164. 


22  THE  AMERICAN    COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [334 

freedom,  by  such  masters,  to  their  slaves,  and  of  the  slave's 
refusal  to  go  free.  In  succeeding  pages  of  this  study  in- 
stances will  also  be  pointed  out  of  negroes  who  requested  to 
be  purchased  by  benevolent  men.  Rev.  R.  R.  Gurley,  sec- 
retary of  the  American  Colonization  Society,  tells  of  an 
interesting  native  African  sold  to  a  South  Carolina  slave- 
holder. The  negro's  name  was  Moro;  he  was  educated  a 
Mohammedan. 

About  twenty  years  ago,  while  scarcely  able  to  express  his  thoughts 
intelligently  on  any  subject  in  the  English  language,  he  fled  from  a 
severe  master  in  South  Carolina,  and  on  his  arrival  at  Fayetteville 
was  seized  as  a  runaway  slave,  and  thrown  into  jail.  His  peculiar 
appearance,  inability  to  converse,  and  particularly  the  facility  with 
which  he  was  observed  to  write  a  strange  language  attracted  much 
attention,  and  induced  his  present  humane  and  Christian  master  to 
take  him  from  prison  and  finally,  at  his  earnest  request,  to  become 
his  purchaser.  His  gratitude  was  boundless,  and  his  joy  to  be 
imagined  only  by  him,  who  has  himself  been  relieved  from  the  iron 
that  enters  the  soul.  Since  his  residence  with  General  Owen  [his 
purchaser]  he  has  worn  no  bonds  but  those  of  gratitude  and  affec- 
tion. .  .  .  Being  of  a  feeble  constitution,  Moro's  duties  have  been  of 
the  lightest  kind  and  he  has  been  treated  rather  as  a  friend  than  a 
servant.  The  garden  has  been  to  him  a  place  of  recreation  rather 
than  toil,  and  the  concern  is  not  that  he  should  labor  more  but  less.18 

There  are  significant  statements  in  a  note,  appended  by 
himself,  to  the  will  of  Reverend  Thomas  S.  Witherspoon, 
of  Alabama : 

It  will  be  plainly  seen  that  my  intention  is  to  liberate  them  [six 
slaves]  by  colonizing  them  in  some  of  the  colonies  of  free  blacks. 
This  I  would  do  now,  but  they  utterly  refuse  to  leave  me,  protesting 
that  they  will  not  leave  me  until  my  death.  ...  I  cannot  meet  death 
in  peace  while  the  consciousness  of  the  fact  is  left  that  these  faithful 
and  pious  servants  are  to  be  left  in  bondage.  I  feel  that  I  am  re- 
sponsible to  God  for  them.  ...  I  am  a  Presbyterian  minister.  .  .  . 
My  slaves  I  inherited  from  my  father  and  through  my  deceased  wife, 
all  but  one,  whom  I  purchased  to  keep  him  with  his  wife.19 

It  must  not  be  supposed  that  the  upper  South  was  igno- 
rant of  the  comparative  cost  of  slavery.  In  a  report  of  the 
Delaware  Auxiliary  Colonization  Society,  in  1825,  we  find 
these  words :  "  It  [slavery]  depreciates  our  soil,  lessens  our 
agricultural  revenue,  and  like  the  lean  kine  of  Egypt,  eats 

18  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Gurley  to  Board 
of  Managers,  May  21,  1837. 

19  Ibid.,  J.  M.  Witherspoon  to  the  President,  Dec.  15,  1845. 


335]  THE   FREE   NEGRO  AND  THE  SLAVE  23 

up  the  fat  of  the  land.  It  will  hardly  admit  of  a  question, 
but  that  the  Southern  section  of  our  country  would,  in  a 
few  years,  be  richer  without  one  slave,  than  it  is  now  with 
i,6oo,ooo."20  And  two  years  later  J.  H.  B.  Latrobe,  for 
many  years  President  of  the  Colonization  Society,  declared : 

When  white  labour  becomes  so  cheap  that  three  men  can  be  hired 
all  the  year,  and  ten  at  harvest,  for  less  than  the  families  of  thirteen 
working  negroes  can  be  supported  for  (including  the  services  of  chil- 
dren), all  the  twelve  months,  to  do  the  labour  of  a  farm,  these 
slaves  will  be  the  ruin  of  their  possessors.  This  is  coming  to  pass 
rapidly,  and  will  be  the  result  of  the  present  state  of  things  and  the 
gradual  increase  of  a  white  population,  before  many  years,  in  all 
those  States  which  do  not  cultivate  rice  and  cotton — slave  labour 
must  be  rendered  valueless  there  by  competition  from  the  very  place 
we  are  labouring  to  build  up  [Liberia] — cotton  and  rice  cultivated 
by  free  labour  in  Africa,  ought  according  to  all  politico-economical 
calculations,  to  undersell  the  cotton  and  rice  cultivated  by  slave 
labour  to  the  South;  when  this  is  the  case,  Carolina  and  her  brothers 
and  sisters,  or,  Carolina  and  Company,  will  receive  a  shock  which 
for  some  years  may  prostrate  them,  but  it  will  be  like  that  weakness 
which  is  the  immediate  effect  of  a  medicine  which  in  the  end  cures 
the  patient.11 

In  the  Virginia  Convention  of  1829,  C.  F.  Mercer  pointed 
out  the  fact  that,  in  1817,  the  land  of  Virginia  was  valued 
at  $206,000,000,  while  in  1829  the  same  land  was  valued  at 
only  $96,000,000;  and  that,  while  the  average  value  of 
slaves,  in  Virginia,  was  $300  in  1817,  the  average  value,  in 
1829,  was  only  $I5O.22  Henry  Clay,  for  years  President  of 
the  Society,  expressed  very  clearly  his  view  in  1830.  As 
the  population  of  the  United  States  increased,  he  predicted, 
the  European  would  gain  ground,  numerically,  over  the 
negro;  hence,  white  labor  would  become  more  abundant. 
Given  enough  laborers,  free  labor  is  always  cheaper  than 
slave  labor.  Therefore  the  value  of  slaves  would  become 
smaller  and  smaller;  masters  would  discourage  the  raising 
of  negro  children ;  and  slavery  would  become  so  obviously 
unprofitable  that  emancipations  would  become  more  and 
more  common.  He  added : 

20  African  Repository,  vol.  i,  pp.  343-344. 

21  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Latrobe,  Jan. 
5,  1827. 

22  African  Repository,  vol.  v,  p.  377. 


24  THE  AMERICAN   COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [336 

What  has  tended  to  sustain  the  price  of  slaves  in  the  U.  S.  has 
been  .  .  .  especially  the  increasing  demand  for  cotton,  and  the  con- 
sequent increase  of  its  cultivation.  The  price  of  cotton  .  .  .  regu- 
lates the  price  of  slaves  as  unerringly  as  any  one  subject  whatever 
is  regulated  by  any  standard.  .  .  .  The  adult  slaves  will,  in  process 
of  time,  sink  in  value  even  below  $100  each,  I  have  no  doubt.28 

Mrs.  Ann  R.  Page,  than  whom  no  more  conscientious 
individual,  more  consistent  opponent  of  slavery,  or  more 
zealous  friend  of  the  American  Colonization  Society  lived 
in  the  State  of  Virginia,  wrote,  in  1831:  "The  expense  of 
slave  estates  keeps  Virginians,  at  least  many,  unable  to  give 
freely,  unless  a  new  spirit  of  stronger  faith  and  love  could 
actuate  them  to  deny  accustomed  self-indulgencies."  "If 
ever  I  get  out  of  debt,  all  I  hope  to  want  with  money  is  to 
further  its  [the  American  Colonization  Society's]  plan."24 
In  1834  Garritt  Meri weather  wrote : 

I  am  a  slaveholder  and  have  it  in  contemplation  to  liberate  several 
of  my  slaves,  provided,  they  could  be  removed  to  Liberia  at  a  cost 
I  could  afford.  But  mine  is  the  common  misfortune  of  most  slave- 
holders— a  nominal  wealth  only;  the  shadow  and  not  the  substance, 
the  reality.  We  may  give  to  Freedom— to  Liberia — this  delusive 
property  (and  I  dare  say  with  the  majority  of  masters  it  would  be 
gain)  but  here  would  end  the  boon,  for  with  them  could  be  added 
no  purse,  or  means  of  emigration  or  settlement.  There  are  many, 
very  many,  slaveholders,  I  am  sure,  who  would  cheerfully  relinquish 
all  their  slave  property  to  Liberia,  could  they  afford  the  means  of 
equipment  and  settlement  or  temporary  maintenance  of  such  manu- 
mitted slaves.25 

The  dread  of  insurrections  only  added  to  the  problem. 
In  1791  the  slaves  of  Hayti  revolted.  For  a  time  the  island 
was  without  a  civil  government;  and  when  in  1801  there 
was  an  emergence  of  order,  it  was  in  the  form  of  a  negro 
government.  In  1800,  a  negro,  Gabriel  by  name,  of  Han- 
over County,  Virginia,  planned  an  insurrection.  In  1822, 
Denmark  Vesey,  of  Charleston,  was  hanged  before  he  was 
able  to  execute  a  plot.26  In  August,  1831,  the  whole  upper 
South  was  profoundly  moved  by  the  Southampton  mas- 

23  Ibid.,  1830,  pp.  1-25. 

24  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Mrs.  A.  R.  Page 
to  the  Secretary,  Millwood,  Va.,  March  26,  1831. 

25  Ibid.,  Meriweather  to  Gurley,  April  23,  1834. 

26  A.  B.  Hart,  Slavery  and  Abolition,  pp.  157,  163. 


337]  THE   FREE   NEGRO  AND  THE   SLAVE  25 

sacre.     In  October  of  that  year,  Collin  H.  Minge,  of  Vir- 
ginia, wrote : 

I  am  ...  sure  that  there  is  not  an  enemy  to  the  cause  of  Coloni- 
zation in  Virginia  at  this  time.  The  predictions  of  Mr.  Randolph 
some  years  since  are  now  becoming  true;  the  whites  are  running 
away  from  the  blacks,  the  masters  from  the  slaves,  in  lower  Virginia, 
the  place  of  insurrection.  I  received  an  intimation  from  a  gentle- 
man yesterday  to  go  to  his  house  to  advize  his  negroes,  8  in  number, 
most  young  ones,  to  embark  for  Liberia,  as  he  was  willing  to  eman- 
cipate them.  Our  next  Legislature  I  think  will  do  something.27 

The  feeling  of  alarm  that  came  over  one  of  the  counties 
of  Virginia  in  which  negroes  were  numerous  is  apparent 
from  a  petition  signed  by  one  hundred  and  ninety-five  citi- 
zens of  Northampton  County  and  dated  December  6,  1831, 
just  after  the  Southampton  massacre.  While  it  will  be  evi- 
dent, from  extracts  here  given,  that  there  was  an  urgent 
demand  for  the  removal  of  the  free  negro,  the  demand  arose 
rather  from  the  fear  for  their  personal  safety  among  the 
citizens  than  from  a  desire  to  perpetuate  slavery.  The  peti- 
tion in  part  follows : 

By  the  last  census  of  the  U.  States  it  appears  that  there  are  in 
this  county  3573  whites,  3734  slaves,  and  1334  free  persons  of  colour. 
By  a  comparison  with  the  census  of  preceding  years,  it  also  appears 
that  the  proportion  of  free  persons  of  colour  to  our  white  inhabi- 
tants is  annually  increasing.  .  .  .  The  free  persons  of  colour  in  Vir- 
ginia form  an  anomalous  population,  standing  in  a  relation  to  our 
society,  which  naturally  exposes  them  to  distrust  &  suspicion.  Infe- 
rior to  the  whites  in  intelligence  &  information;  depraved  by  the 
stain  which  attaches  to  their  colour ;  excluded  from  many  civil  privi- 
leges which  the  humblest  white  man  enjoys,  and  denied  all  partici- 
pation in  the  government,  it  would  be  wholly  absurd  to  expect  from 
them  any  attachment  to  our  laws  &  institutions,  or  any  sympathy 
with  our  people.  On  the  other  hand,  the  enjoyment  of  personal 
freedom  is  in  itself  a  sufficient  mark  of  distinction  between  them  & 
our  slaves,  and  elevates  them,  at  least  in  their  own  opinion,  to  a 
higher  condition  in  life.  Standing  thus  in  a  middle  position  between 
the  two  extremes  of  our  society  and  despairing  of  ever  attaining  an 
equality  with  the  higher  grade,  it  is  natural  that  they  should  connect 
themselves  in  feeling  &  interest,  with  the  slaves  among  whom  many 
of  their  domestic  ties  are  formed,  and  to  whom  they  are  bound  by 
the  sympathies  scarcely  less  strong,  which  spring  from  their  common 
complexion.  Independent,  therefore,  of  any  particular  facts  calcu- 
lated to  excite  our  alarms,  the  worst  evils  might  justly  be  appre- 
hended from  such  an  increase  of  their  numbers  as  would  give  them 
confidence  in  their  physical  power,  while  it  would  enlarge  their 

27  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  C.  H.  Minge  to 
Gurley,  Oct.  22,  1831. 


26  THE  AMERICAN   COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [338 

means  of  information,  facilitate  their  intercommunications,  and 
thus  add  to  their  capabilities  of  mischief.  Unhappily,  however,  this 
is  no  longer  a  subject  of  mere  speculation.  The  scenes  which  have 
recently  passed  around  us  contain  a  melancholy  &  impressive  lesson 
upon  the  subject,  to  which  the  most  careless  and  supine  among  us 
cannot  be  unattentive.  The  caution  which  these  scenes  suggest  is 
of  peculiar  importance  to  us.  From  the  number  of  our  free  negroes, 
and  from  the  idle  &  vicious  habits  of  most  of  them,  we  have  stronger 
reason  than  exists  in  most  of  our  counties,  to  suspect  dangerous 
intrigues  with  our  slaves ;  nor  can  we  be  insensible  to  the  great  aid 
which  our  slaves  would  derive  from  that  source,  in  any  actual  at- 
tempts against  us. 

They  therefore  appealed  to  the  legislature  for  permission  to 
borrow  $15,000.00,  to  be  repaid  by  the  citizens  of  the  county 
levying  upon  themselves  a  tax  equal  to  the  existing  State 
tax.  They  further  resolved :  "  That  our  representatives  be 
instructed  to  vote  for  every  measure,  whether  of  a  general 
or  local  character,  which  may  have  for  its  object  the  re- 
moval of  the  free  people  of  colour  from  the  State  at  large 
or  any  part  thereof."  And  the  motive  is  clearly  set  forth 
in  the  concluding  portion  of  the  petition:  "The  evil  of 
which  we  complain  is  found  to  be  no  longer  endurable,  with- 
out the  most  serious  dangers  to  the  peace  &  security  of  our 
county,  &  we  are  willing  to  rid  ourselves  of  it  at  every  sac- 
rifice &  every  hazard."28 

In  December  of  the  same  year,  a  member  of  the  Virginia 
Legislature  wrote  to  the  Colonization  Society  asking  whether 
a  very  large  number  of  immigrants,  such  as  Virginia  might 
desire  to  send  at  once  to  the  Liberian  colony,  could  be  re- 
ceived on  short  notice.  He  said : 

The  subject  of  colonising  the  free  people  of  colour  in  this  common- 
wealth, and  such  of  the  slaves  as  their  proprietors  may  voluntarily 
emancipate,  (if  indeed  it  be  not  made  to  comprise  a  scheme  of  gen- 
eral emancipation,)  will  be  acted  upon  by  the  Virginia  Legislature 
during  it's  present  session.  As  a  member  of  that  body  feeling  the 
liveliest  interest  in  that  part  of  the  African  race  who  have  resi- 
dence among  us,  as  well  as  in  the  general  welfare  of  our  country, 
upon  which  they  are  admitted  to  be  a  lamentable  burden,  it  wouJd 
be  highly  culpable  in  me  to  remain  inactive,  during  the  agitation  of 
the  subject. 

The  horrible  affair  of  Southampton  has  given  rise  to  new  and 
decided  feelings  in  the  breasts  of  Virginians  from  every  part  of 
the  State,  in  regard  to  the  black  population.  And  the  friends  o,f 

•8  Legislative  Petitions,  MS.,  Dec.  6,  1831,  Virginia  State  Library. 


339J  THE   FREE   NEGRO  AND  THE   SLAVE  2/ 

Colonization,  (I  had  almost  said,  of  emancipation)  may  now  find 
willing  and  anxious  agents,  to  push  to  the  utmost  practicable  extent 
their  philanthropic  wishes. 

The  following  January  he  wrote : 

The  committee  to  which  was  referred  the  subject  of  the  free 
people  of  colour  was  organized  on  Monday  last,  and  have  proceeded 
to  discuss  some  of  the  delicate  questions  relating  to  it.  Upon  one 
point  there  is  no  difference  of  opinion;  I  mean  as  to  the  expediency 
of  adopting  a  scheme  at  once  for  the  removal  of  the  free  people  of 
colour,  and  such  of  the  other  class  as  their  proprietors  may  volun- 
tarily manumit.  Thus  far  the  people  are  prepared  to  go,  as  shewn 
in  their  accumulated  memorials  from  every  portion  of  the  State. 
Many  are  for  going  much  farther,  and  comprehending  the  whole 
black  class  in  a  system  of  gradual  reduction.  .  .  .  The  Legislature 
are  certainly  ready  to  make  the  most  ample  appropriation,  efficiently 
to  carry  through  the  first  named  object.  Different  sums  are  men- 
tioned, from  100,000  to  300,000  dollars  annually.  .  .  ,29 

Opinion  in  the  border  slave  States  at  this  time  undoubt- 
edly was:  (i)  the  abolition  of  slavery,  if  practicable,  con- 
sistently with  the  safety  of  the  whites  and  the  welfare  of 
the  blacks,  was  desirable;  (2)  any  scheme  of  immediate  and 
unconditional  emancipation  was  wholly  impracticable;  (3) 
the  tendency  among  newly  emancipated  negroes  was  to  in- 
cite the  slaves  to  revolt ;  (4)  emancipated  negroes,  as  a  class, 
had  not  been  benefited,  but,  on  the  contrary,  had  been  actu- 
ally the  losers  by  the  fact  of  emancipation.  The  opinion 
was  widespread  in  the  whole  South  that  if  the  time  ever 
came  when  two  races,  as  distinct  as  the  white  and  the  black, 
occupied  the  same  territory,  and  were  numerically  not 
greatly  unequal,  a  war  of  extermination  was  almost  inevita- 
ble. It  has  been  seen  that  DeTocqueville  held  distinctly  to 
this  view  and,  although  he  was  altogether  an  opponent  of 
the  principle  of  slavery,  the  only  suggestions  he  had  to  offer 
to  the  South  were  amalgamation  with  the  blacks,  and  a 
continuance  of  the  system  of  slavery  as  long  as  possible. 
To  look  for  amalgamation  was  to  look  for  the  mountains 
to  remove  themselves ;  and  yet,  up  to  a  period  as  late  as 
1840,  the  leaders  of  thought,  except  in  the  Southeastern 
States,  were  far  from  willing  to  admit  that  the  other  was 
the  only  alternative. 

M  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  C.  S.  Carter, 
Dec.  22,  1831 ;  Jan.  6,  i8j2. 


28  THE  AMERICAN   COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [340 

Not  long  after  the  organization  of  the  Colonization  So- 
ciety, Dr.  William  Thornton  expressed  the  conviction  that 
there  "  never  could  exist  a  sincere  union  between  the  whites 
and  the  blacks,  even  on  admitting  the  latter  to  the  rights  of 
freemen."30  In  1827,  Clay  asked : 

What  is  the  true  nature  of  the  evil  of  the  existence  of  a  portion 
of  the  African  race  in  our  population  ?  It  is  not  that  there  are  some, 
but  that  there  are  so  many  among  us  of  a  different  caste,  of  a  dif- 
ferent physical,  if  not  moral,  constitution,  who  never  could  amalga- 
mate with  the  great  body  of  our  population.  .  .  .  Any  project,  there- 
fore, by  which,  in  a  material  degree,  the  dangerous  element  in  the 
general  mass,  can  be  diminished  or  rendered  stationary,  deserves 
deliberate  consideration.81 

Jonathan  Mayhew  Wainwright,  in  1829,  asked  a  similar 
question : 

What  is  to  be  done  with  our  rapidly  increasing  coloured  popula- 
tion ?  Any  one  who  can  think,  and  compute  numbers,  and  who  will 
look  at  our  censuses  of  population,  must  be  convinced  that  the  reply 
to  this  inquiry  should  call  forth  all  the  wisdom,  foresight,  patriotism, 
and  benevolence  of  our  whole  country.  A  refuge  must  be  prepared 
for  these  people.32 

W.  M.  Atkinson,  one  of  the  most  prominent  Coloriizationists 
in  the  State  of  Virginia,  said : 

On  one  point  we  differ  toto  caelo — I  have  no  doubt  that  emanci- 
pation without  emigration,  would  utterly  ruin  the  State.  I  further 
believe  that  it  would  end  in  the  extermination  of  the  one  race  or 
the  other — and  if  so,  I  do  not  doubt  it  would  be  the  African.  Hence 
I  must  oppose  it,  everywhere,  and  by  all  gentlemanly  and  Christian 
means.  Hence,  too,  one  reason  of  my  zeal  for  colonization,  as  indis- 
pensable to  that  other  indispensable  measure  [emancipation]. 

I  succeeded  today  in  obtaining  a  decree  for  the  emancipation  of 
Elder's  slaves,  but  his  cause  will  go  to  the  court  of  appeals.33 

In  1830,  the  Senate  of  Massachusetts,  in  a  resolution 
highly  commendatory  of  the  Colonization  project,  stated: 
"  In  those  States  where  slavery  is  tolerated,  as  well  as  in 
the  others,  where  it  has  ceased  to  exist,  the  dangers  and 
difficulties,  emanating  from  the  great  and  increasing  num- 
bers of  free  persons  of  colour,  had  long  been  the  subjects  of 

30  African  Repository,  vol.  i,  pp.  87-88. 
1  Ibid.,  vol.  ii,  pp.  334-345- 

82  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Wainwright  to 
Gurley,  Jan.  5,  1829. 
33  Ibid.,  Atkinson  to  Gurley,  Nov.  10,  1831. 


34 1 ]  THE   FREE   NEGRO  AND  THE  SLAVE  29 

deep  individual  solicitude  and  inquiry,  and  of  numerous 
legislative  enactments."34    In  1839  Clay  declared: 

In  the  slave  States  the  alternative  is,  that  the  white  man  must 
govern  the  black,  or  the  black  govern  the  white.  In  several  of  these 
States  the  number  of  slaves  is  greater  than  that  of  the  white  popu- 
lation. An  immediate  abolition  of  slavery  in  them,  as  these  ultra- 
abolitionists  propose  would  be  followed  by  a  desperate  struggle  for 
immediate  ascendancy  of  the  black  race  over  the  white  race,  or 
rather  it  would  be  followed  by  instantaneous  collisions  between  the 
two  races,  which  would  break  out  into  a  civil  war  that  would  end 
in  the  extermination  or  subjugation  of  the  one  race  or  the  other.35 

This  alarm  at  the  rapid  increase  of  the  free  negro  popu- 
lation was  an  important  cause  of  enactments  of  slavehold- 
ing  States  prohibiting  emancipations.  Within  a  fortnight 
of  the  organization  of  the  Colonization  Society,  a  memorial 
was  presented  to  Congress,  by  its  Board  of  Managers,  in 
which  this  rapid  increase  was  remarked  on  in  the  following 
words :  "  The  evil  has  become  so  apparent,  and  the  necessity 
for  a  remedy  so  palpable,  that  some  of 'the  most  consider- 
able of  the  slaveholding  States,  have  been  induced  to  impose 
restraints  upon  the  practice  of  emancipation,  by  annexing 
conditions,  which  have  no  effect  but  to  transfer  the  evil 
from  one  State  to  another."38  In  reply  to  memorials  from 
Colonizationists,  the  Legislature  of  Virginia  stated : 

The  extent  of  this  evil  [the  increase  in  the  number  of  free  negroes] 
may  be  fairly  estimated,  by  a  reference  to  our  Statute  book.  The 
laws  intended  either  to  prevent  or  to  limit  its  effects,  are  of  a  char- 
acter, which  nothing,  but  the  extreme  necessity  of  the  case,  could 
ever  justify,  to  a  community  of  republicans;  and  the  obligation  to 
resort  to  them,  is  sufficient  to  command  the  serious  attention  of 
every  enlightened  patriot. 

To  considerations  such  as  these,  may  be  traced  the  policy  first 
resorted  to  by  the  Legislature  of  Virginia  in  1805,  of  arresting  the 
progress  of  emancipation,  by  requiring  the  speedy  removal  from  the 
State,  of  all  to  whom  its  privileges  might  be  extended.37 

In  an  address  before  the  New  Hampshire  Colonization 
Society,  Daniel  Dana  said: 

It  is  a  fact,  given  us  on  the  most  unquestionable  authority,  that 
there  are  now  in  the  Southern  States  of  our  Union,  hundreds,  and 

34  African  Repository,  vol.  vi,  pp.  144-147. 
85Ibid.,  vol.  xv,  pp.  50-64. 

36  Origin,  Constitution,  and  Proceedings,  American  Colonization 
Society,  MS.,  pp.  13-19. 
87  African  Repository,  vol.  v,  pp.  50-55. 


3O  THE  AMERICAN    COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [342 

even  thousands  of  proprietors,  who  would  gladly  give  liberty  to  their 
slaves,  but  are  deterred  by  the  apprehension  of  doing  injury  to  their 
country,  and  perhaps  to  the  slaves  themselves.  It  is  a  fact  that  in 
the  States  of  Maryland  and  Virginia  alone,  there  were  fifteen  years 
since,  63,000  free  people  of  colour.  It  is  likewise  a  fact,  that  within 
a  few  years  past,  more  than  500  slaves  have  been  emancipated,  in 
the  State  of  Virginia,  by  only  three  proprietors.  Indeed,  so  preva- 
lent has  been  the  disposition  of  Southern  proprietors,  for  many 
years,  to  give  liberty  to  their  slaves,  that  this  condition  of  things  has 
excited  a  serious  alarm.  The  legislatures  of  several  States  have 
interposed  their  authority,  and  prohibited  the  emancipation  of  slaves, 
except  on  the  condition  of  their  being  transferred,  to  some  other 
State.38 

The  House  of  Representatives  of  Maryland,  in  1831, 
passed  the  following  resolutions: 

That  as  philanthropists  and  lovers  of  freedom,  we  deplore  the 
existence  of  slavery  amongst  us,  and  would  use  our  utmost  exertions 
to  ameliorate  its  condition,  yet  we  consider  the  unrestricted  power 
of  manumission  as  fraught  with  ultimate  evils  of  a  more  dangerous 
tendency  than  the  circumstance  of  slavery  alone,  and  that  any  act, 
having  for  its  object  the  mitigation  of  these  joint  evils,  not  incon- 
sistent with  other  paramount  considerations,  would  be  worthy  the 
attention  and  deliberation  of  the  representatives  of  a  free,  liberal- 
minded  and  enlightened  people. 

Resolved,  That  we  consider  the  colonization  of  free  people  of 
colour  in  Africa  as  the  commencement  of  a  system,  by  which,  if 
judicious  encouragement  be  afforded,  these  evils  may  be  measurably 
diminished.89 

It  is  a  significant  fact,  however,  that  these  individual  and 
legislative  objections  to  the  right  of  emancipation  were  con- 
fined to  cases  in  which  the  emancipated  remained  within  the 
limits  of  the  State.  In  explanation  of  this  fact,  students  of 
slavery  have  urged  that  the  real  reasons  behind  such  objec- 
tions was  either  the  desire  of  pro-slavery  men  to  "  boost " 
the  price  of  slaves  by  reducing  to  a  minimum  the  competi- 
tion of  free-negro  labor,  or  the  fear,  among  the  slave- 
holders, that  an  increasing  free  negro  element  was  danger- 
ous to  the  security  of  their  slave  property.  Undoubtedly 
both  of  these  explanations  contain  an  element  of  truth ;  but 
there  is  abundant  evidence  to  show  that  the  leading  single 
cause  of  this  widespread  attitude  was  the  deliberate  and  firm 
conviction  that  the  free  negro  was  a  source,  and  a  most 

88  Ibid.,  vol.  i,  p.  144. 

89  Ibid.,  vol.  vii,  p.  30. 


343]  THE    FREE    NEGRO   AND   THE   SLAVE  3! 

fruitful  source,  of  lawlessness  and  crime,  of  social  and 
political  insecurity.  The  degrading  influence  of,  and  the 
degraded  condition  of,  the  free  negro  were  recognized  and 
remarked  upon  from  every  quarter  of  the  Union.  It  was 
not  a  sectional  opinion ;  it  was  a  national  one.  Of  this  im- 
portant free  negro  problem  DeTocqueville  writes : 

Whoever  has  inhabited  the  United  States  must  have  perceived 
that  in  those  parts  of  the  Union  in  which  the  negroes  are  no  longer 
slaves,  they  have  in  nowise  drawn  nearer  to  the  whites.  On  the 
contrary,  the  prejudice  of  the  race  appears  to  be  stronger  in  the 
States  which  have  abolished  slavery  than  in  those  where  it  still 
exists;  and  nowhere  is  it  so  intolerant  as  in  those  States  where 
servitude  never  has  been  known.  The  electoral  franchise  has  been 
conferred  upon  the  negroes  in  almost  all  the  States  in  which  slavery 
has  been  abolished ;  but  if  they  come  forward  to  vote,  their  lives 
are  in  danger.  .  .  .  The  gates  of  Heaven  are  not  closed  against  these 
unhappy  beings;  but  their  inferiority  is  continued  to  the  very  con- 
fines of  the  other  world ;  when  the  negro  is  defunct,  his  bones  are 
cast  aside,  and  the  distinction  of  condition  prevails  even  in  the 
equality  of  death. 

In  the  South,  where  slavery  still  exists,  the  negroes  are  kept  less 
carefully  apart;  they  sometimes  share  the  labour  and  the  exertions 
of  the  whites ;  the  whites  consent  to  intermix  with  them  to  a  certain 
extent,  and  although  the  legislation  treats  them  more  harshly  the 
habits  of  the  people  are  more  tolerant  and  compassionate.  .  .  . 
Thus  it  is,  in  the  United  States,  that  the  prejudice  which  repels  the 
negroes  seems  t'o  increase  in  proportion  as  they  are  emancipated, 
and  inequality  is  sanctioned  by  the  manners  while  it  is  effaced  from 
the  laws  of  the  country.40 

Memorialists  from  the  Richmond  and  Manchester  Aux- 
iliary Colonization  Society,  about  1825,  called  attention  to 
the  fact  that  of  37,000  free  negroes  in  Virginia,  not  two 
hundred  were  proprietors  of  land.41  About  the  same  time 
the  New  York  Tract  Magazine  stated : 

Free  blacks  are  collected  in  large  towns  and  cities,  where  a  great 
portion  of  them  are  found  in  the  abodes  of  poverty  and  vice,  and 
become  the  tenants  of  poor  houses  and  prisons.  As  a  proof  .  .  . 
the  following  striking  fact  has  been  mentioned.  The  State  of  Penn- 
sylvania, before  the  last  census,  had  a  population  of  upwards  of 
800,000;  the  number  of  free  blacks  was  about  26,000,  and  yet  one 
half  of  the  convicts  in  the  State  prison  were  free  blacks.42 

The  Charlottesville,  Virginia,  Central  Gazette  declared: 
"that  slavery  is  unjust  by  the  laws  of  nature,  is  a  truth 

40  DeTocqueville,  vol.  i,  p.  383  ff. 

41  African  Repository,  vol.  i,  p.  67. 

42  Ibid.,  vol.  i,  pp.  91-92. 


32  THE  AMERICAN    COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [344 

which  every  man  derives  directly  from  the  infallible  oracles 
of  his  own  conscientious  convictions,"  and  at  the  same  time 
it  declared  that  the  emancipation  of  the  slaves,  without  their 
removal  from  the  State,  "  would  be  pernicious."*3  In  1827, 
a  citizen  of  Chillicothe  wrote:  "In  most  of  the  towns  of 
Ohio,  there  are  a  number  of  free  blacks,  who  with  few  ex- 
ceptions, are  little  less  than  a  nuisance  and  their  numbers 
are  every  year  increasing  by  immigration,  as  well  as  other 
causes.  All  of  the  whites  would  willingly  do  something  to 
free  themselves  from  this  evil.44 

Gerrit  Smith,  who  had  thought  of  establishing  a  school 
for  free  negroes,  "so  that  they  might  take  knowledge  and 
Christianity  to  the  natives  of  Africa,"  announced,  in  1827 : 

I  am  recently  getting  off  this  scheme.  The  turn  that  negro-learning 
takes  in  this  country  is  not  always  favorable.  It  is  certainly  not  so 
with  the  editors  of  the  Freedom's  Journal,  a  paper  I  was  at  first  dis- 
posed to  patronize  and  which  I  still  take.  .  .  .  My  heart  is  fully  set 
on  discharging  the  patriotic  duty  of  contributing  to  relieve  our  coun- 
try of  its  black  population.45 

A  Virginia  clergyman,  writing  to  the  Colonization  Society 
in  1829,  states: 

Having  formerly  set  free  a  number  of  coloured  people  who  are 
now  vagabonds,  I  have  done  them  no  profit,  but'  injured  society. 
For  this  there  is  no  remedy,  as  I  have  no  control  over  them.  Those 
still  in  my  possession,  I  cannot  conscientiously  emancipate,  unless 
they  shall  be  removed  by  the  Society  to  Liberia.  A  Kst  of  six,  which 
I  wish  transferred  to  the  Colony,  was  last  fall  furnished  to  the 
Society,  and  entered  upon  its  books.  I  wish  them  to  be  called  for, 
as  I  am  old,  and  desire  the  business  may  be  completed  before  I 
quit  my  earthly  station.46 

In  1829  the  President  of  Union  College  stated: 

Our  manumitted  bondmen  have  remained  already  to  the  third  and 
fourth,  as  they  will  to  the  thousandth  generation — a  distinct,  a  de- 
graded, and  a  wretched  race.  When  therefore  the  fetters,  whether 
gradually  or  suddenly,  shall  be  stricken  off,  and  stricken  off  they 
will  be,  from  those  accumulating  millions  yet  to  be  born  in  bond- 
age, it  is  evident  that  this  land,  unless  some  outlet  be  provided,  will 
be  flooded  with  a  population  as  useless  as  it  will  be  wretched ;  a 

43  Ibid.,  vol.  i,  p.  215  ff. 

44  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Wm.  Graham 
to  Gurley,  Feb.  10,  1827. 

45  Ibid.,  G.  Smith  to  Gurley,  Oct.  10,  1827. 

46  African  Repository,  vol.  v,  pp.  177-178. 


345]  THE   FREE   NEGRO  AND  THE   SLAVE  33 

population  which,  with  every  increase,  will  detract  from  our  strength, 
and  only  add  to  our  numbers,  our  pauperism  and  our  crimes. 
Whether  bond  or  free,  their  presence  will  be  forever  a  calamity. 
Why,  then,  in  the  name  of  God,  should  we  hesitate  to  encourage 
their  departure?41 

Arthur  Tappan,  soon  to  be  a  disciple  of  William  Lloyd 
Garrison,  had,  himself,  experienced  a  problem  whose  solu- 
tion evidently  gave  him  concern;  although,  had  he  been  a 
Southerner,  he  would  doubtless  have  quietly  added  another 
item  to  his  account  for  incidental  expenses.  Slave  traders 
had  brought  to  America  and  sold  two  brothers,  the  sons  of 
Prince  Abduhl  Rahhahman,  a  native  African  prince.  These 
had  secured  their  freedom  and  were,  at  the  time  Tappan 
wrote,  in  New  York,  being  cared  for  by  Tappan  himself. 

I  feel  it  to  be  incumbent  on  me  to  advise  with  the  managers  of 
your  Society  before  sending  the  children  of  Prince  Abduhl  Rah- 
hahman to  Norfolk  [to  be  transported  to  Africa],  respecting  the 
single  son.  Without  any  motive  that  we  discover,  having  a  suffi- 
ciency of  food,  etc.,  he  has  been  guilty  of  stealing  some  poultry  and 
has  been  liberated  from  prison,  ...  by  his  brother's  borrowing  and 
paying  a  sum  of  money.  I  can  regard  this  as  no  less  than  an  indi- 
cation of  a  thievish  propensity  that  will  be  likely  to  show  itself 
whenever  a  good  opportunity  offers.48 

Of  this  class  of  persons,  Henry  Clay  said:  "They  are 
not  slaves,  yet  they  are  not  free. — The  laws,  it  is  true,  pro- 
claim them  free ;  but  prejudices,  more  powerful  than  laws, 
deny  them  the  privileges  of  freemen.  .  .  .  They  crowd  our 
large  cities  .  .  .  where  those  who  addict  themselves  to  vice 
can  best  practice  and  conceal  their  crimes."  He  also  called 
attention  to  the  adoption,  by  the  city  of  Cincinnati,  of  meas- 
ures to  expel  all  "who  could  not  give  guaranties  of  their 
good  behavior."49  President  Duer,  of  Columbia,  said  of 
the  free  blacks : 

Their  numbers  are  constantly  increasing  in  a  formidable  ratio. 
At  the  South  they  are  looked  upon  with  suspicion,  and  almost  with 
abhorrence.  At  the  North  they  are  regarded  as  an  inferior  caste, 
and  consequently  deprived  of  every  incentive  to  virtuous  action.  .  .  . 
Conscious  that  they  can  never  surmount  these  barriers,  they  natu- 

47  Ibid.,  vol.  v,  pp.  277-278. 

48  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Tappan  to  Gur- 
ley,  Sept.  n,  1830. 

49  African  Repository,  March,  1830,  pp.  1-25. 


34  THE  AMERICAN   COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [346 

rally  become  improvident — and  from  improvidence  the  descent  ia 
easy  to  recklessness,  profligacy,  and  crime.  To  the  fidelity  of  this 
inference  our  criminal  calendar  bears  melancholy  witness.  Com- 
paring the  relative  proportions  of  white  and  colored  population  in 
our  State,  more  than  nine-tenths  of  those  who  are  arraigned  at  our 
police  establishments  and  courts  of  sessions,  and  who  occupy  the 
cells  of  our  bridewells,  penitentiaries,  and  State  prisons,  are,  we 
are  constrained  to  say,  of  the  latter  description.60 

Reverend  William  Meade,  later  Bishop  of  Virginia,  the 
first  agent  of  the  Colonization  Society  and  a  man  who, 
though  by  no  means  wealthy,  gave  hundreds  of  dollars  to 
the  cause,  and  who  hated  the  system  of  slavery  as  sincerely 
as  did  any  son  of  New  England,  and  said  of  it  that  it  is 
"  one  of  the  most  deadly  evils  that  ever  afflicted  a  nation," 
wrote,  in  1832: 

I  have  thought,  read,  conversed,  written,  and  spoken  much  on  this 
subject  for  the  last  fifteen  years.  I  have  travelled  through  all  the 
length  and  breadth  of  our  land,  and  witnessed  the  condition  of  the 
negroes,  bond  and  free;  conversed  fully  with  them,  their  owners, 
and  their  philanthropic  friends ;  and  every  year  only  rivets  the  con- 
viction more  deeply  in  my  mind,  that  to  do  them  real  good  they 
must  be  separated  from  those  of  a  different  color.51 

C.  F.  Mercer,  for  a  committee  of  the  House  of  Representa- 
tives, at  Washington,  replied  to  memorials  from  the  friends 
of  Colonization,  presented  in  1827.  He  called  attention  to 
the  fact  that  one  of  the  important  results  of  the  large  num- 
ber and  the  degraded  condition  of  the  free  blacks  in  the 
South,  was  to  impose  further  restraints  upon  the  practice 
of  emancipation.52 

Reverend  William  Henry  Foote  wrote  of  the  free  colored 
population  of  Hampshire  County,  Virginia,  now  West  Vir- 
ginia :  "  They  are  here  a  miserable  race.  ...  I  have  a  num- 
ber of  colored  members  in  my  church  (about  30)  and  only 
two  are  free,  and  they  are  old.  The  slaves  are  better  in 
every  respect.  And  in  sending  to  Africa  I  should  from 
this  region  prefer  for  the  good  of  the  Colony  a  manumitted 

80  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Duer  to  Gur- 
ley,  Dec.  10,  1831. 

61  African  Repository,  vol.  viii,  pp.  86-87;  Letters  of  American 
Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Meade  to  Samuel  Wilkeson,  Dec.  14, 1839. 

62  27th  Cong.,  3d  sess.,  H.  Kept.  no.  283,  pp.  408-414. 


347]  THE   FREE   NEGRO  AND  THE   SLAVE  35 

black  to  one  of  these  already  free  or  born  free."53  In  1836, 
Citizens  of  Dauphin  County,  Pennsylvania,  petitioning  Con- 
gress in  behalf  of  Colonization,  spoke  in  no  uncertain  tones 
of  the  unworthiness  and  degradation  of  the  free  negro 
population.54  Judge  Samuel  Wilkeson,  of  New  York,  later 
general  agent  for  the  Colonization  Society,  wrote  to  Lewis 
Sheridan,  a  free  negro  of  respectability,  a  very  successful 
farmer  of  North  Carolina,  and  himself  the  owner  of  nine- 
teen slaves: 

The  high  character  which  you  have  acquired  in  North  Carolina, 
for  moral  worth  and  mercantile  ability,  might  be  regarded  as  evi- 
dence that  the  colored  man  stands  on  ground  equally  elevated  as 
the  white  man,  making  allowance  only  for  the  difference  of  educa- 
tion, and  political  condition.  .  .  .  Feeling  a  great  desire  for  the  eleva- 
tion of  the  colored  man,  I  embraced  every  opportunity  by  several 
visits  to  the  Southern  and  Southwestern  States  of  making  myself 
acquainted  with  the  condition  of  both  slaves  and  free  people  of 
colour,  and  their  susceptibility  of  elevation  in  this  country.  ...  I 
am  satisfied  that  the  coloured  man  is  as  capable  of  acquiring  trades 
as  the  white  man,  and  that  the  reason  he  is  sa  seldom  found  in  the 
Middle  and  Eastern  States  carrying  on  mechanic  business,  is  not  for 
want  of  ability  to  acquire  the  knowledge  and  skill,  but  on  account  of 
the  difficulties  and  discouragements  incident  to  his  condition.  .  .  . 
The  merchant  will  not  employ  them  as  clerks ;  the  mechanic  will  not 
employ  them  as  journeymen;  should  he  perchance  find  such  employ- 
ment, he  applies  for  board  and  is  refused— other  workmen  will  not 
eat  with  him ;  thus  he  meets  at  the  very  outset  in  life  with  difficulties 
which  he  cannot  surmount. 

Wilkeson  proposed  that  he  should  be  one  of  ten  men  to 
organize  a  ship  line  between  the  United  States  and  Liberia 
to  be  turned  over  to  free  negroes  in  order  to  give  them  en- 
couragement in  their  mercantile  ambitions.55 

A  free  negro  from  South  Carolina  had  been  induced  to 
go  to  the  North.  Writing  to  friends  in  his  native  city,  he 
requested  the  names  of  the  members  of  the  State  Legisla- 
ture, in  order  that  he  might  urge  them  to  repeal  the  law 
forbidding  free  blacks  to  come  into  the  State,  for  he  desired 
to  return.  He  says : 

Although  I  have  visited  almost  every  city  and  town,  from  Charles- 
ton, South  Carolina,  to  Portland,  Maine,  I  can  find  no  such  home 

53  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Foote  to  Gur- 
ley,  Sept.  19,  1833. 

6*  African  Repository,  vol.  xii,  pp.  82-85. 
65  Ibid.,  vol.  xiv,  pp.  58-60. 


36  THE  AMERICAN    COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [348 

and  no  such  respectable  body  of  colored  people,  as  I  left  in  my 
native  city  Charleston.  The  law  in  my  adopted  city,  Philadelphia, 
when  applied  to  colored  people,  in  opposition  to  white  people,  is  not 
as  good  as  in  Charleston,  unless  the  former  has  respectable  white 
witness  to  sustain  it.  ...  All  the  advantage  that  I  see  by  living  in 
Philadelphia  is,  that  if  my  family  is  sick,  I  can  send  for  a  doctor 
at  any  time  of  the  night  without  a  ticket.58 

And  the  following  extract  from  Marville  H.  Smith's  let- 
ter seems  to  bear  out  the  assertion  of  De  Tocqueville,  that 
the  free  negro  was  nowhere  so  badly  treated  as  in  those 
parts  of  the  Union  in  which  slavery  never  existed.  Smith 
was  a  free  negro  who  acted  as  the  spokesman  for  a  group 
of  eighteen,  who  had  gone  to  Illinois. 

We  are  ready  to  start  from  Shawneetown  at  any  moment,  and 
wish  the  time  to  come  as  soon  as  possible  [the  time  to  go  to  Li- 
beria] ;  for  though  we  are  free  in  name  we  are  not  free  in  fact  We 
are  in  as  bad,  or  worse  condition  than  the  slaves  of  which  you 
speak,  being  compelled  to  leave  the  State,  or  give  security,  and 
those  of  the  whites  who  would  befriend  us  are  debarred  by  the  fear 
of  public  opinion.  If  only  those  who  deserve  such  treatment,  if 
any  do,  were  the  only  ones  to  suffer  we  should  be  content;  but  on 
the  contrary,  if  one  misbehaves,  all  the  colored  people  in  the  neigh- 
borhood are  the  sufferers,  and  that  frequently  by  unlawful  means ; 
dragged  from  our  beds  at  the  hour  of  midnight,  stripped  naked,  in 
presence  of  our  children  and  wives,  by  a  set  of  men  alike  lost  to 
mercy,  decency  and  Christianity,  and  flogged  till  they  are  satisfied, 
before  we  know  for  what;  and  when  we  are  informed,  it  is  prob- 
ably the  first  time  we  heard  of  the  offence.  Such  is  our  situation 
and  such  the  condition  from  which  your  Society  can  extricate  us. 
We  deem  it  worse  than  slavery.  We  say  again  we, wish  to  go  to 
Liberia,  and  if  no  way  else  is  provided,  we  had  as  lief  soon  indent 
ourselves  to  the  Society  for  life  for  our  passage,  so  we  can  live 
among  our  own  color.  Let  me  know  as  soon  as  possible,  whether 
you  can  help  us,  and  how  soon,  and  how  much.67 

Roger  M.  Sherman,  of  Connecticut,  said  of  the  emanci- 
pated slave:  "He  is  liable  to  be  taken  and  sold  again  into 
slavery,  unless  removed  from  the  State.  Remove  him  to  a 
free  State,  and  he  is  cut  off  from  the  hopes  of  any  political 
standing  and  condemned,  by  the  unalterable  usages  of 
society,  to  a  state  of  degradation."58  Edward  Everett  de- 
scribed their  condition  as  one  of  "disability,  discourage- 

88  Ibid.,  vol.  xv,  pp.  178-180. 

87  Ibid.,  vol.  xviii,  p.  221. 

88  Ibid.,  vol.  xx,  pp.  294-296. 


349]  THE    FREE    NEGRO   AND   THE   SLAVE  37 

ment,  and  hardship."59    Reverend  John  Orcutt,  of  Connec- 
ticut, a  traveling  agent  of  the  Society,  reported : 

Not  only  are  free  negroes  forbidden  to  come  into  Indiana  by  ex- 
press statute,  but  it  is  made  a  penal  offense  for  a  white  person  to 
induce  such  immigration.  .  .  .  When  a  State  constitution  was  adopted 
in  Oregon,  four-fifths  of  the  electors  said  by  their  vote  we  will  not 
have  slavery!  and  they  also  said  by  about  the  same  majority,  "we 
will  have  no  free  negroes  1 "  Illinois  too,  has  a  similar  prohibitory 
law  against  free  negroes.  .  .  .  Already  in  the  Eastern  States,  the 
black  man  finds  himself  on  equal  footing  with  the  whites  nowhere, 
except  in  the  State  prisons,  where  he  is  on  the  same  level,  and  fully 
represented !  No  wonder  that  some  of  the  free  colored  people  at 
the  North  should  begin  to  inquire  with  solicitude  what  they  sha.ll 
do.  I  saw  several  at  the  West  who  said,  "We  must  go  some- 
where I  "eo 

Up  to  1830  the  opinion  prevailed  throughout  the  United 
States,  unless,  indeed,  we  except  Georgia  and  South  Caro- 
lina, that,  both  for  the  sake  of  the  free  and  unhampered 
development  of  his  possibilities,  and  for  the  purpose  of 
stimulating  more  frequent  emancipations,  the  free  negro 
must  be  sent  to  a  home  without  the  limits  of  any  one  of  the 
States.61  And  scores  of  slaveholders  after  1817  offered 
liberty  to  their  slaves  on  the  condition  of  their  willingness 
to  emigrate  to  Liberia.  John  A.  Dix,  speaking  before  the 
New  York  State  Colonization  Society,  in  1830,  said:  "The 
mass  of  crime  committed  by  Africans  is  greater,  in  propor- 
tion to  numbers,  in  the  non-slaveholding  than  in  the  slave- 
holding  States;  and  as  a  rule  the  degree  of  comfort  enjoyed 
by  them  is  inferior.  This  is  not  an  argument  in  favor  of 
slavery;  but  it  is  an  unanswerable  argument  in  favor  of 
rendering  emancipation  and  colonization  co-extensive  with 
each  other."62 

69  Address  at  Annual  Meeting,  American  Colonization  Society, 
Jan.  18,  1853. 

60  Minutes  of  Board  of  Directors  of  American  Colonization  So- 
ciety, MS.,  Jan.  16,  1861. 

t  61  Origin,  Constitution,  and  Proceedings  of  American  Coloniza- 
tion Society,  MS.,  vol.  i,  pp.  120-121;  vol.  i,  pp.  127-128;  African 
Repository,  vol.  i,  p.  89,  reprint  from  the  Albany  Argus;  vol.  i, 
p.  182 ff.,  reprint  from  Niles  Register;  vol.  i,  p.  285;  vol.  v,  p.  4, 
speech  of  Clay  before  the  Kentucky  Colonization  Society,  Dec.  17, 
1829;  vol.  v,  pp.  50-55;  vol.  vi,  pp.  144-147;  vol.  xiii,  p.  38;  vol.  xxi, 
pp.  145-149;  27th  Cong.,  3d  sess.,  H.  Rept.  No.  283,  passim. 

62  African  Repository,  vol.  vi,  pp.  163-169. 


38  THE  AMERICAN   COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [350 

One  or  two  quotations,  from  many  that  could  be  given, 
will  illustrate  the  point  of  view  from  which  a  large  class  of 
Southern  slaveholders  looked  at  the  problem  of  emancipa- 
tion. Reverend  C.  J.  Gibson  wrote  from  Petersburg, 
Virginia : 

I  have  belonging  to  me  two  families  of  servants,  whom  I  am 
anxious  to  emancipate,  if,  by  any  means,  I  can  settle  them  in  Liberia. 
The  duties  of  the  Holy  Ministry,  .  .  .,  render  me  utterly  unfit  to  be 
a  faithful  Christian  Master  and  incline  me  to  desire  this  step  for 
the  benefit  of  my  own  highest  interests  and  those  of  my  sacred 
office.  At  the  same  time,  I  feel  bound  to  consult  the  best  good  of 
my  servants,  and  in  releasing  them  from  my  care,  to  place  them  in 
a  situation,  where  the  blessings  of  freedom  may  really  be  enjoyed. 
This,  I  am  very  sure,  cannot  be  found  in  our  own  country,  and  I  am 
therefore  determined  not  to  free  them  unless  they  can  be  sent  to 
Africa.63 

It  will  not  be  without  interest  or  profit  to  read  the  fol- 
lowing letter  from  an  unlearned  Southern  slaveholder: 

Dear  Sir  at  the  Death  of  my  Father  I  inherited  a  Negro  boy  by 
Name  (Moses)  from  his  Est.  and  by  Misfortunes  and  the  Impru- 
dence of  my  Youth  I  had  to  sell  him  Some  year  or  two  after  which 
Time.  I  sought  and  found  the  Lord  precious  to  my  Immortal  Soul 
Soon  after  this  Happy  Change  the  Grace  of  God  began  to  Shed 
Light  upon  my  mind  I  read  the  Holy  Laws  of  God  and  found  therein 
this  Command  do  to  Others  as  you  would  Others  Should  do  to  you 
I  then  began  to  Ask  My  Self  if  I  had  of  been  Moses'  Slave  and  he 
my  Master  if  I  would  have  had  him  to  of  Sold  me  to  a  man  who 
would  have  kept  me  in  Slavery  all  my  days  on  Earth  and  Perhaps 
without  the  Comforts  of  Life  and  in  Perfect  Ignorance  and  degra- 
dation. I  readily  answered  the  Question  and  determined  by  the 
Help  of  God  to  buy  Moses  if  ever  I  Got  able  if  he  would  agree  to 
go  to  the  Colony  Settled  on  the  Shores  of  Africa  I  was  at  that 
Time  Very  Poor  as  to  this  World's  Goods  I  however  went'  to  work 
and  after  some  Years  Toil  I  found  I  had  the  means  to  Buy  Moses 
I  saw  him  and  Talked  with  him  about  going  to  Africa  and  he  de- 
clined I  then  Told  him  I  would  leave  him  to  consider  on  the  Subject 
and  when  ever  he  got  his  Consent  to  go  I  would  buy  him  but  that 
I  would  buy  him  on  No  Other  Terms  as  I  did  not  wish  to  own  any 
Slaves  Some  Year  or  two  pass'd  by  when  Early  one  Morning  Moses 
made  his  appearance  at  my  door  and  Told  he  wanted  me  to  buy 
him  I  ask'd  him  if  he  had  Consented  to  go  to  the  Colony  he  said 
if  I  would  buy  him  he  would  go  but  he  had  rather  Stay  with  me 
I  told  him  I  would  only  buy  him  on  the  Conditions  he  would  go  to 
the  Colony  (and  then  bought  him  he  was  then  Quite  a  Prayerless 
Wicked  Man  I  thought  it  would  be  best  for  him  that  I  would  keep 
him  a  year  or  two  and  try  by  the  assistance  of  the  Lord  to  be  In- 
strumental in  his  Salvation  in  12  or  18  Months  after  he  Profess'd 

63  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Gibson  to  Gur- 
ley,  Jan.  26,  1844. 


35*]  THE   FREE    NEGRO   AND  THE   SLAVE  39 

the  Religion  of  the  Savior  Since  which  Time  say  12  or  18  Months 
he  has  to  all  Human  Appearance  been  a  Very  Pious  Man  and  I  do 
hope  and  think  he  is  now  traveling  that  Road  that  Leads  to  the  fair 
Climes  of  Immortal  Joys.  I  have  been  Striving  in  my  poor  way  to 
do  my  duty  to  this  poor  Coloured  Man  the  Time  has  Arrived  when 
I  think  I  ought  to  send  him  on  to  the  Colony  and  although  he  is  a 
poor  Colour'd  Man  I  feel  distress  at  Parting  with  him  but  a  sense 
of  my  duty  urges  me  and  I  now  wish  to  get  Some  Instruction  and 
assistance  from  You  by  what  Vessel  I  can  send  him  and  from  what 
place  and  at  What  Time  will  it  start  and  for  what  Settlement  I 
want  him  Carried  to  a  Healthy  Settlement  what  Implements  is  nec- 
essary and  what  Kind  of  Clotheing  and  how  Shall  I  get  him  to  the 
place  where  the  Vessel  is  to  Sail  from  and  to  whom  Shall  I  direct 
him  to  be  put  in  the  Care  of  and  what  Shall  I  do  with  the  Money  I 
give  him  to  Carry  with  him  Your  kind  Instruction  in  this  Matter 
will  Very  Much  Oblige  yours  with  Much  esteem 

SAMUEL  O.  Moon.64 

A  Kentucky  slaveholder,  whose  slaves  had  been  left  be- 
hind, when  a  vessel  sailed  with  emigrants  to  Liberia  wrote 
to  the  Colonization  Society :  "  I  cannot  be  a  slaveholder.  I 
must  get  rid  of  my  slaves  in  some  way.  To  set  them  free 
in  Kentucky  I  cannot  and  will  not.  I  fear  I  shall  have. to 
adopt  the  revolting  expedient  of  selling;  I  dread  this  but  I 
must  do  something."65  W.  M.  Atkinson,  of  Virginia,  be- 
lieved that,  because  of  the  necessity  of  preserving  the  safety 
of  the  whites,  Virginia  would  never  give  up  slavery  unless 
provision  should  be  made  for  the  removal  of  the  blacks.66 
A  similar  opinion  was  expressed  by  General  Bayly,  of  the 
same  State.87 

The  idea  of  the  colonization  of  the  negro  sprang  full 
grown  from  the  brain  of  no  individual.  Henry  Clay  thought 
that  it  was  the  product,  not  of  the  minds  of  men,  but  of  the 
very  requirements  of  the  times,  because  it  was  "  an  obvious 
remedy."  As  early  as  1773  a  correspondence  was  begun 
between  Doctor  Samuel  Hopkins,  of  Rhode  Island,  and 
Reverend  Ezra  Stiles,  later  President  of  Yale  College. 
Hopkins  desired  to  send  two  or  three  negroes  of  Rhode 
Island  to  the  coast  of  Guinea.  Stiles  thought  that  not 
fewer  than  thirty  or  forty  could  be  profitably  sent.  The 

«4  Ibid.,  Moon  to  Gurley,  August  17,  1835. 
"5  Ibid.,  Triplett  to  W.  McLain,  Jan.  16,  1846. 

86  Ibid.,  Atkinson  to  Gurley,  Sept.  27,  1831. 

87  African  Repository,  vol.  xiv,  pp.  119-120. 


4O  THE  AMERICAN   COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [352 

purpose  of  these  men,  however,  was  purely  missionary; 
they  did  not  discuss  the  desirability  of  transporting  the  free 
colored  population  back  to  their  native  land,  although  it  is 
evident  that  Doctor  Stiles  thought  one  effect  of  such  a  set- 
tlement on  the  coast  of  Africa  might  be  to  have  some  influ- 
ence in  putting  an  end  to  the  African  slave  trade.68  The 
Revolutionary  War  cut  short  all  hopes  of  carrying  out  these 
plans.  In  1777  a  committee  of  the  Virginia  Legislature,  of 
which  Jefferson  was  chairman,  proposed  the  gradual  eman- 
cipation of  slaves,  and,  at  the  same  time,  their  exportation.69 
There  can  be  no  doubt  that  between  1785  and  1817,  Doc- 
tor William  Thornton  exerted  a  powerful  influence  in  favor 
of  colonization.  He  was  in  correspondence  with  British 
leaders  in  the  movement  for  the  transportation  of  their 
blacks,  and  which,  under  the  direction  of  Granville  Sharpe 
and  others,  resulted  in  the  establishment  of  the  British 
colony  of  Sierra  Leone  on  the  West  coast  of  Africa.  In 
an  undated  letter  "To  the  Black  Inhabitants  of  Pennsyl- 
vania, assembled  at  one  of  their  stated  meetings  in  Phila- 
delphia," he  wrote : 

It  is  in  contemplation  by  the  English  to  make  a  free  settlement  of 
Blacks  on  the  Coast  of  Africa,  which  they  have  already  begun.  .  .  . 
They  are  desirous  of  knowing  if  any  of  the  Blacks  of  this  country 
be  willing  to  return  to  that  Region  which  their  fathers  originally 
possessed,  and  finding  many  in  Boston,  Providence  and  Rhode  Island 
very  anxious  of  embarking  for  Africa,  wish  also  to  be  informed  if 
any  of  the  Blacks  in  Pennsylvania  are  inclined  to  settle  there.70  . 

Indeed,  soon  after  the  preliminary  meeting  which  resulted 
in  the  organization  of  the  American  Colonization  Society, 
Thornton  wrote  to  Henry  Clay  that,  during  the  winter  of 
1786-87,  while  traveling  in  Rhode  Island  and  Massachusetts, 
he  found  many  free  blacks  and  became  deeply  interested  in 
them.  He  had  already  corresponded  with  friends,  members 
of  the  Sierra  Leone  Society,  and  he  became  anxious  to 
know  whether  the  free  blacks  of  those  two  States  desired 

68  Literary  Diary  of  Ezra  Stiles,  vol.  i,  pp.  363-364. 
68  African  Colonization,  "An  Inquiry  into  the  Origin,  Plan,  arid 
Prospects  of  the  American  Colonization  Society,"  p.  4. 
70  Thornton  Papers,  MS.,  vol.  xiv.    Pages  not  numbered. 


353]  THE   FREE   NEGRO  AND  THE   SLAVE  4! 

to  be  transported  to  the  British  Colony.  He  had  a  meeting 
called,  at  which  hundreds  of  that  class  were  present,  and 
he  was  later  informed  by  them  that  2,000  of  them  would  go. 
The  Massachusetts  Legislature  seemed  interested,  and  many 
members  promised  liberal  aid,  until  they  heard  that  he  pro- 
posed to  settle  the  emigrants  under  British  protection. 
They  desired  the  settlement  to  be  made  "  in  the  most  south- 
ern part  of  the  back  country  between  the  whites  and  In- 
dians." To  this  scheme  Thornton  objected.71  Thornton 
assures  us,  however,  that  about  the  year  1788,  "  the  Ameri- 
cans in  New  England  were  desirous  of  sending  all  the  free 
blacks  from  that  country,  and  offered  ships  and  every  neces- 
sary for  their  support."72  Thornton  himself  at  one  time 
had  made  many  preparations  to  go  to  Africa  to  superintend 
such  a  colony;  but  his  plan  did  not  materialize.78  Doctor 
Hopkins,  whose  letter  to  Stiles  is  quoted  above,  was,  in 
1789,  in  correspondence  with  Thornton  on  the  subject  of 
colonization;  and  in  1791  he  made  an  effort  to  secure  the 
incorporation  of  the  Connecticut  Emancipation  Society,  one 
of  whose  objects  was  the  colonization  of  free  blacks.74 

In  December,  1800,  the  Virginia  Legislature  requested 
Governor  Monroe  to  correspond  with  the  President  of  the 
United  States  "  on  the  subject  of  purchasing  lands  without 
the  limits  of  this  State,"  whither  obnoxious  persons  might 
be  sent.  This  resolution  was  called  forth  by  a  conspiracy 
of  slaves  in  or  near  Richmond.  By  law  the  conspirators 
were  guilty  of  a  capital  offence;  but  the  Legislature  pro- 
posed transportation,  as  an  act  of  clemency.  This  corre- 
spondence was  productive  of  no  material  results.  But  the 
following  year  the  Legislature  directed  the  Governor  to 
continue  the  correspondence,  suggesting  this  time  that  it 
might  be  desirable  to  locate  a  colony  outside  the  limits  of 
the  United  States,  a  view  in  which  President  Jefferson  fully 

71  Ibid.,  vol.  xiv,  letter  to  Clay,  no  date. 
1  Ibid.,  vol.  xiv,  no  name,  no  date. 

7>  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Mrs.  Anna  M. 
Thornton,  Jan.  18,  1831. 

74  Half-Century  Memorial,  American  Colonization  Society,  1867, 
pp.  62-65. 


42  THE  AMERICAN    COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [354 

concurred.  The  essential  difference  between  these  two  Vir- 
ginia resolutions  was  that  the  first  contemplated  merely  the 
establishment  of  a  penal  colony,  while  the  second  proposed 
to  provide  an  outlet  for  the  whole  of  the  free  black  popula- 
tion, and  to  provide  for  those  who  desired  to  emancipate 
their  slaves  an  opportunity  to  do  so  without  danger  to  the 
State.  President  Jefferson  corresponded,  though  without 
success,  with  the  British  authorities  regarding  the  incor- 
poration of  the  free  blacks  of  this  country  into  the  Sierra 
Leone  colony.75 

Samuel  J.  Mills  of  Connecticut,  deservedly  called  the 
father  of  the  foreign  missionary  enterprise  in  the  United 
States,  came  to  the  conclusion,  after  a  tour  of  the  South- 
western part  of  the  United  States,  that  "  we  must  save  the 
negroes,  or  the  negroes  will  ruin  us."  He  thought  the 
South  at  that  time  so  well  disposed  towards  the  negro  as  to 
be  willing  to  enter  heartily  into  a  colonization  scheme.76 

Paul  Cuffee,  a  negro  sea  captain,  a  resident  of  Massachu- 
setts, and  the  son  of  a  native  African  who  had  been  sold 
into  slavery  but  who  had  later  secured  his  own  freedom, 
transported  from  the  United  States  to  Africa  thirty-eight 
persons  of  color,  probably  the  first  company  of  negro  emi- 
grants whose  object  was  resettlement  in  the  land  from  which 
they  or  their  fathers  had  come.  The  expense  of  the  voyage, 
nearly  $4000,  was  borne  by  Cuffee  himself  and  the  negroes 
were  taken  for  settlement  to  the  Sierra  Leone  colony.  From 
the  point  of  view  of  actual  accomplishment  the  name  of 
Paul  Cuffee  must  find  a  place  on  the  list  of  those  whose 
efforts  and  whose  views  made  possible  the  organization  of 
the  American  Colonization  Society,  although  his  company 
set  sail  in  1815,  almost  two  years  before  the  formal  organi- 
zation of  the  American  Colonization  Society,  and  the  voyage 
was  undertaken  upon  Cuffee's  personal  responsibility  and 

78  Mafhew  Carey,  Reflections,  p.  6 ;  Half-Century  Memorial, 
American  Colonization  Society,  1867,  pp.  62-65. 

76  Half-Century  Memorial,  American  Colonization  Society,  1867, 
pp.  66-68. 


355]  THE   FREE    NEGRO   AND   THE   SLAVE  43 

without  cooperation  or  help  from  either  the  government  or 
any  philanthropic  association.77 

Reverend  Robert  Finley  of  New  Jersey  has  generally 
been  considered  the  father  of  the  American  Colonization 
Society.  If  by  this  it  is  meant  that  he,  more  than  any  other 
man,  brought  about  the  meeting  which  resulted  in  the  or- 
ganization of  that  Society,  no  violence  is  done  to  truth; 
although  it  could  with  equal  justice  and  probably  more  accu- 
racy be  said  that  the  Society  was  the  result  of  the  efforts 
of  Thornton,  Mills,  and  Finley,  north  of  Mason  and  Dixon's 
line,  and  of  Charles  Pent  on  Mercer,  Francis  Scott  Key,  and 
E.  B.  Caldwell,  south  of  that  line. 

At  least  as  early  as  February,  1815,  Finley  had  become 
deeply  interested  in  the  organization  of  a  colonization  move- 
ment. He  talked  of  colonization,  wrote  of  colonization, 
made  a  visit  to  Washington  in  the  interest  of  colonization, 
and  led  in  the  movement  which  resulted  in  a  public  meeting 
at  Princeton  in  furtherance  of  the  plan.  But  while  he  had 
been  at  work  in  New  Jersey,  Mercer  had  not  been  idle  in 
Virginia.  Each,  it  seems,  worked  at  this  time  independently 
of  the  other.  Mercer  had  been  elected  a  member  of  the 
Virginia  Legislature.  He  had  learned  of  the  two  resolu- 
tions passed  by  that  body  on  the  subject  of  colonization,  in 
1800  and  1802 — both  passed  under  a  pledge  of  secrecy. 
Mercer  was  not  under  this  pledge,  and  he  published  abroad 
the  action  taken  at  that  time.  A  new  interest  was  aroused. 
He  secured  the  passage  of  a  resolution  which  met,  in  most 
respects,  the  views  of  Doctor  Finley.  This  resolution  was 
passed  in  the  Senate  with  but  one  dissenting  vote,  and  in 
the  House  by  a  vote  of  132  to  I4.78  The  governor  was 
thereby  instructed  to  correspond  with  the  President  of  the 
United  States  for  the  purpose  of  obtaining  territory  upon 
the  coast  of  Africa,  or  upon  the  shore  of  the  North  Pacific, 
or  at  some  other  place,  "to  serve  as  an  asylum  for  such 

77  J.  W.  Lugenbeel,  Sketch  of  the  History  of  Liberia,  MS. 

78  Half-Century  Memorial,  American  Colonization  Society,  1867, 
pp.  68-71;  Carey,  Reflections,  p.  6;  African  Colonization,  "An  In- 
quiry into  the  Origin,  Plan,  and  Prospects  of  the  American  Coloni- 
zation Society,"  pp.  4-5. 


44  THE  AMERICAN    COLONIZATION    SOCIETY  [356 

persons  of  colour  as  are  now  free,  and  may  desire  the  same, 
and  for  those  who  may  hereafter  be  emancipated  within  this 
commonwealth."79  While  Finley  and  Mercer  worked  in 
New  Jersey  and  Virginia,  Key  was  at  work  in  Maryland, 
and  Doctor  E.  B.  Caldwell,  a  brother-in-law  of  Finley,  was 
busy  in  the  District  of  Columbia;  and  when  it  was  pro- 
posed to  hold  a  meeting  in  Washington,  December  21,  1816, 
the  leaders  were  thoroughly  interested  and,  to  a  degree  at 
least,  the  public  mind  had  been  prepared. 

And  now  by  way  of  summary.  In  1815  New  England 
recognized  the  evil  of  slavery  to  be  a  national  evil.  New 
England  felt  the  responsibility  of  helping,  not  driving,  the 
South  to  get  rid  of  that  institution.  Cooperation,  not  an- 
tagonism, was  to  be  the  means  employed  by  each  section  in 
its  relations  with  the  other.  To  the  upper  South  slavery 
was  a  problem,  because  it  had  grown  to  be  one  of  those 
underlying  bases  in  the  economic  life  of  the  South ;  because 
its  immediate  abolition  would  mean,  in  many  cases,  a  sud- 
den change  from  affluence  to  poverty;  because  it  was  sin- 
cerely believed  that  the  sudden  emancipation  of  many  thou- 
sands of  slaves  in  the  South  would  be  an  added  cruelty  to 
the  class  of  improvident  free  negroes ;  because  of  the  very 
fact  that  the  liberation  of  one  slave  meant  the  addition  of 
one  free  negro.  For  the  free  negro  was  also  a  problem. 
He  was  a  problem  because  of  the  instances  in  the  mind  of 
every  tolerably  read  Southerner,  of  outrages  and  insurrec- 
tions of  the  blacks  against  the  whites,  in  countries  in  which 
the  population  of  each  was  not  greatly  unequal ;  because  of 
the  opinion  that  prevailed  in  every  part  of  the  Union  that 
the  negro  could  never  rise  to  the  limit  of  his  possibilities  so 
long  as  he  remained  in  this  country ;  because  in  his  degraded 
condition  he  was  a  source  of  danger,  only  and  always,  to 
the  community  in  which  he  lived.  These  were  the  prob- 
lems, and  together  they  made  up  the  great  negro  problem 
of  that  time.  There  were  four  solutions  proposed :  ( i )  the 
immediate  and  unconditional  abolition  of  slavery;  (2)  the 
perpetuation  of  slavery  as  long  as  possible;  (3)  the  policy 

70  African  Repository,  vol.  i,  pp.  249-251. 


357]  THE   FREE   NEGRO  AND   THE   SLAVE  45 

of  non-interference  with  the  natural  course  of  events;  (4) 
colonization. 

The  first  of  these  proposed  solutions  was  supposed  to  be, 
and  was,  utterly  impracticable,  the  paramount  importance 
of  the  preservation  of  the  Union  from  a  dissolution,  either 
actual  or  seriously  attempted,  being  at  once  taken  for 
granted.  For  it  is  utterly  impossible  to  reconcile  with  the 
statements  of  either  the  leaders  or  the  leading  opponents  of 
Garrisonian  Abolition  the  statement  of  Professor  A.  B. 
Hart  that  "it  must  not  be  supposed  that  .  .  .  even  the 
[anti-slavery]  agitators  realized  that  slavery  had  the  latent 
power  of  dividing  the  Union  and  bringing  about  civil  war." 
Time  and  again  they  were  warned  of  just  this  latent  power; 
and  the  Garrisonians  expressed  their  satisfaction  with  the 
result,  should  that  result  be  even  the  dissolution  of  the 
Union. 

The  second  proposed  solution  was  as  impracticable  as  the 
first.  The  institution  of  slavery  was  doomed  to  die.  The 
question  of  prime  importance  was,  not  whether  or  not 
slavery  could  continue  to  exist  as  a  system,  but  what  form 
its  destruction  should  take.  The  Garrisonians  and  the  cot- 
ton gin  had  not  yet  filled  the  upper  South  with  a  lingering 
wish  that  it  might  survive,  and  a  lingering  hope  that  it 
would.  In  1815,  the  leaders  of  thought  in  the  upper  South 
were  definitely  set  against  the  second  proposed  solution. 

The  third  was  so  seldom  advocated  by  men  of  pronounced 
influence,  that  a  consideration  of  its  merits  is  unnecessary, 
in  this  study. 

Unquestionably,  the  one  supposed  solution  to  which  the 
leaders  of  thought  in  every  part  of  the  Union,  except  possi- 
bly the  extreme  South,  turned  was  that  of  colonization. 
The  free  negro  would  be  transported  to  the  land  whence 
his  fathers  came ;  the  danger  from  the  alarming  increase  in 
the  free  negro  population  would  vanish  as  ghosts  vanish 
with  the  coming  of  the  morning;  slaveholders  could  then 
safely  and  gradually  emancipate  their  slaves,  and  the  negro 
problem  would  be  solved.  And  now  let  us  consider  the 
channel  through  which  the  experiment  was  made. 


CHAPTER  II 

ORGANIZATION,  PURPOSE,  AND  EARLY  YEARS  OF  THE 
AMERICAN  COLONIZATION  SOCIETY 

As  a  result  of  the  efforts  of  the  brothers-in-law,  Rev. 
Robert  Finley  of  New  Jersey,  and  Dr.  E.  B.  Caldwell  of 
Washington,  a  meeting  was  held  in  that  city  December  16, 
1816.  The  general  purpose  was  the  discussion  of  negro 
colonization.  Bushrod  Washington  presided,  and  among 
the  speakers  were  Henry  Clay  and  John  Randolph  of  Roa- 
noke.  Five  days  later  a  second  meeting  was  held,  presided 
over  by  Clay.  Among  resolutions  adopted,  the  following 
is  of  interest : 

The  situation  of  the  free  people  of  colour  in  the  United  States 
has  been  the  subject  of  anxious  solicitude,  with  many  of  our  most 
distinguished  citizens,  from  the  first  existence  of  our  country  as  an. 
independent  nation;  but  the  great  difficulty  and  embarrassment  at- 
tending the  establishment  of  an  infant  nation  when  first  struggling 
into  existence,  and  the  subsequent  great  convulsions  of  Europe  have 
hitherto  prevented  any  great  national  effort  to  provide  a  remedy  for 
the  evils  existing  or  apprehended.  The  present  period  seems  pecu- 
liarly auspicious  to  invite  attention  to  this  important  subject,  and 
gives  a  well  grounded  hope  of  success.  The  nations  of  Europe  are 
hushed  into  peace;  unexampled  efforts  are  making  in  various  part's 
of  the  world  to  diffuse  knowledge,  civilization,  and  the  influence  of 
the  Christian  religion.  .  .  .  Desirous  of  aiding  in  the  great  cause  of 
philanthropy,  and  of  promoting  the  prosperity  and  happiness  of  our 
country,  it  is  recommended  by  this  meeting,  to  form  an  association 
or  Society  for  the  purpose  of  giving  aid  and  assisting  in  the  coloni- 
zation of  the  free  people  of  colour  in  the  United  States.1 

E.  B.  Caldwell,  John  Randolph,  Richard  Rush,  Gen.  Wal- 
ter Jones,  Francis  Scott  Key,  Robert  Wright,  James  H. 
Blake,  and  John  Peter  were  appointed  to  present  a  memo- 
rial to  Congress,  requesting  federal  aid  in  procuring  terri- 
tory in  Africa  or  elsewhere  for  the  carrying  out  of  their 
design;  Key,  Washington,  Caldwell,  James  Breckenridge, 

1  Origin,  Constitution,  and  Proceedings  of  American  Colonization 
Society,  MS.,  vol.  i,  pp.  1-3. 

46 


359]  ORGANIZATION,  PURPOSE,  EARLY   YEARS  47 

Gen.  Walter  Jones,  Rush,  and  W.  G.  D.  Worthington  were 
appointed  to  prepare  a  constitution  and  rules. 

At  a  third  meeting,  December  28,  there  was  adopted  a 
constitution,  in  which  the  sole  object  of  the  organization 
w_as  stated  to  be  "  to  promote  and  execute  a  plan  for  coloniz- 
ing (with  their  consent)  the  Free  People  of  Colour  resid- 
ing in  our  country,  in  Africa,  or  such  other  place  as  Con- 
gress shall  deem  most  expedient.  And  the  society  shall  act 
to  effect  this  object,  in  cooperation  with  the  General  Gov- 
ernment, and  such  of  the  States  as  may  adopt  regulations 
upon  the  subject."2  A  president,  eight  vice-presidents,  a 
secretary,  a  treasurer,  and  a  recorder  were  to  be  chosen.  A 
board  of  managers,  composed  of  these  officers  and  twelve 
other  members  of  the  Society,  was  to  constitute  the  central 
organization.  Societies  organized  in  the  United  States, 
working  with  the  same  object  as  that  of  the  parent  Society, 
and  contributing  to  the  funds  of  the  central  treasury,  were 
to  be  considered  auxiliary  to  it. 

A  great  deal  has  been  written  regarding  the  ulterior  mo- 
tives of  those  who  in  its  early  days  controlled  the  Society. 
Yet,  even  during  the  bitter  decade  from  1830  to  1840,  The 
Liberator  admitted  many  a  time  the  sincerity  of  motive  and 
the  nobility  of  design  of  those  whose  active  interest  brought 
the  Colonization  Society  into  being.  The  quarrel  was  not 
brought  about,  it  was  said,  because  the  movement  had  been 
dug  up  out  of  the  miry  clay;  it  was  rather  because  it  had 
cast  itself  down  from  the  height  on  which  it  was  born.  It 
will,  therefore,  be  safe  to  assume  that  those  leaders  who 
have  left  behind  them  a  record  of  the  motives  of  both  them- 
selves and  their  coadjutors,  have  spoken  from  their  hearts. 

No  more  credible  witnesses  could  be  found  to  represent 
respectively,  the  northern  and  southern  portions  of  the  Mid- 
dle Atlantic  States  than  Robert  Finley,  of  New  Jersey,  and 
William  H.  Fitzhugh,  of  Virginia.  Finley,  whose  State 
was  not  burdened  with  the  problem  of  slavery,  looked  at 
the  Society  from  the  point  of  view  of  the  welfare  of  the 

2  Ibid.,  vol.  i,  pp.  4-^9. 


48  THE  AMERICAN    COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [360 

free  negro.  Fitzhugh,  a  splendid  example  of  the  influential 
Virginia  slaveholder,  the  owner  of  three  hundred  slaves 
who  were  by  his  will  emancipated  and  offered  special  in- 
ducements if  they  would  consent  to  go  to  Liberia,  heartily 
and  sincerely  opposed  human  slavery,  and  yet,  with  others, 
saw  that  an  epidemic  of  smallpox  could  not  be  relieved  by 
abusive  letters  to  the  victims  by  a  member  of  the  health 
board.  The  South,  to  him  and  to  others,  was  rather  an- 
other Prometheus  Bound,  waiting  for  a  deliverer.  He  saw 
that  the  abolition  of  slavery,  if  it  was  to  come  peaceably, 
must  come  gradually;  that  unconditional  and  immediate 
abolition  would  be  accompanied  by  a  national  upheaval  and 
a  radical  readjustment.  Of  Finley's  motive,  he  himself 
wrote  in  1815: 

The  longer  I  live  to  see  the  wretchedness  of  men,  the  more  I  ad- 
mire the  virtue  of  those  who  devise,  and  with  patience  labor  to 
execute,  plans  for  the  relief  of  the  wretched.  On  this  subject,  the 
state  of  the  free  blacks  has  very  much  occupied  my  mind.  Their 
number  increases  greatly,  and  their  wretchedness  too,  as  appears  to 
me.  Everything  connected  with  their  condition,  including  their 
color,  is  against  them;  nor  is  there  much  prospect  that  their  state 
can  ever  be  greatly  ameliorated,  while  they  continue  among  us. 
Could  not  the  rich  and  benevolent  devise  means  to  form  a  Colony 
on  some  part  of  the  Coast  of  Africa,  similar  to  the  one  at  Sierra 
Leone,  which  might  gradually  induce  many  free  blacks  to  go  and 
settle,  devising  for  them  the  means  of  getting  there,  and  of  protec- 
tion and  support  till  they  were  established.8 

Fitzhugh  wrote  in  1826: 

Our  design  was,  by  providing  an  asylum  on  the  coast  of  Africa, 
and  furnishing  the  necessary  facilities  for  removal  to  the  people  of 
colour,  to  induce  the  voluntary  emigration  of  that  portion  of  them 
already  free,  and  to  throw  open  to  individuals  and  the  States  a  wider 
door  for  voluntary  and  legal  emancipation.  The  operation,  we  were 
aware,  must  be — and,  for  the  interest's  of  our  country,  ought  to  be 
gradual.  But  we  entertained  a  hope,  founded  on  our  knowledge  of 
the  interests  as  well  as  the  feelings  of  the  South,  that  this  operation, 
properly  conducted,  would,  in  the  end,  remove  from  our  country 
every  vestige  of  domestic  slavery,  without  a  single  violation  of  indi- 
vidual wishes  or  individual  rights.4 

Reverend  William  Meade,  later  bishop  of  Virginia,  who 
was  the  first  agent  of  the  Society,  and  to  whom  slavery  was 

8  North  American  Review,  vol.  xxxv,  p.  119. 
*  African  Repository,  vol.  ii,  pp.  254-256. 


361]  ORGANIZATION,  PURPOSE,  EARLY   YEARS  49 

an  "accursed  evil,"  said  in  1825  that,  in  addition  to  the  pur- 
pose of  the  leaders  in  the  colonization  movement,  as  stated 
in  the  constitution,  the  Society 

hopes  to  show  to  the  pious  and  benevolent  how  and  where  they 
may  accomplish  a  wish  near  and  dear  to  many  hearts,  which  is  now 
impossible ;  it  hopes  to  point  out  to  our  several  legislatures,  and  even 
to  the  august  council  of  this  great  nation,  a  way  by  which,  with 
safety  and  advantage,  they  may  henceforth  encourage  and  facilitate 
that  system  of  emancipation  which  they  have  almost  forbidden.5 

As  early  as  1819  such  formidable  opposition  had  reared 
its  head,  from  extremists  of  both  the  pro-slavery  and  the 
anti-slavery  parties,  that  the  managers  of  the  Society  offi- 
cially denied  that  their  design  was  either  "  to  rivet  the  chains 
of  servitude  "  upon  the  negroes  at  the  South,  or  "  to  invade 
the  rights  of  private  property,  secured  by  the  constitution 
and  laws  of  the  several  slave-holding  States."6  Indeed,  it 
is  a  significant  fact,  and  worthy  of  note  at  this  point,  that 
during  the  whole  period  from  1820  to  the  issuance,  by  Abra- 
ham Lincoln,  of  the  Proclamation  of  Emancipation,  the 
bitterest  opponents  Colonization  had  were  those  strange 
bedfellows — New  England  and  South  Carolina.  If  the 
opposition  from  New  England  was  more  pronounced  than 
that  of  the  Carolinians  it  was  largely  because  of  the  fact 
that  the  former  was  better  organized.  It  is  very  probable 
that  never,  in  any  section,  did  Colonization  have  so  few 
friends  as  in  South  Carolina  and  Georgia.  Again  and 
again  the  Society  was  called  upon  to  repeat  its  original 
denial,  and  always  with  as  little  effect. 

The  reason  is  obvious.  Colonization  was  essentially  a 
moderate,  a  middle-State  movement,  counting  among  its 
supporters  the  moderate  men  of  every  part  of  the  Union. 
The  idea  that  called  it  forth  was  a  middle-State  idea.  Ex- 
tremists of  the  far  North  and  the  far  South  were  unable  to 
enter  into  its  feelings.  As  is  likely  to  be  the  case  in  all 
compromise  movements,  extremists  on  either  side  magnified 
possible  objections  into  actually  base  designs.  The  whole 

8  Ibid.,  vol.  i,  pp.  147-150. 

a  Origin,  Constitution,  and  Proceedings  of  American  Colonization 
Society,  MS.,  vol.  i,  pp.  65-74. 

4 


5O  THE  AMERICAN   COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [362 

history  of  Colonization  contains  conclusive  evidence  that 
those  leaders  who  actually  directed  the  affairs  of  the  organi- 
zation, where  they  deviated  at  all  from  the  design  of  the 
Society,  as  expressed  in  its  constitution,  deviated  consis- 
tently on  the  side  of  emancipation.  If  those  who  hesitate 
to  admit  the  purity  of  their  designs  would  go  to  the  trouble 
of  investigating  the  evidence  that  remains,  they  would  prob- 
ably accept  the  defense  of  the  Board  of  Managers  in  1823, 
that  "  they  have  persevered,  confident  that  their  motives  will 
one  day  be  duly  appreciated,  and  trusting  their  cause  to  the 
ruler  of  the  world."7 

Sentiments  of  friends  and  leaders,  and  reasons  given  by 
individuals  for  favoring  the  Colonization  scheme,  cover  a 
wide  range — from  that  of  Gerrit  Smith,  who  said,  while  yet 
a  member  of  the  Colonization  Society,  "We  are  all  aboli- 
tionists at  the  north/'8  to  that  of  a  friend  from  Canton, 
Ohio :  "  Among  the  multitude  carried  away  by  the  floods  of 
abolitionism,  I  remain  an  unwavering  friend  of  the  Coloni- 
zation mode,  of  abolishing  slavery  in  the  United  States,"9 
and  to  that  of  the  Albany  Argus : 

It  seems  to  be  the  middle  ground,  upon  which  the  several  interests 
throughout  the  country,  in  relation  to  slavery,  can  meet  and  act 
together.  It  appears,  indeed,  to  be  the  only  feasible  mode  by  which 
we  can  remove  that  stigma,  as  well  as  danger  from  among  us.  ... 
Gradual  emancipation  .  .  .,  under  the  advantages  of  a  free  govern- 
ment, formed,  in  their  native  land,  by  their  own  hands  ...  is  the 
only  rational  scheme  of  relieving  them  from  the  bondage  of  their 
present  condition.10 

But  those  who  desire  to  consult  a  proslavery  collection  of 
letters  could  not  profitably  spend  their  time  among  the  rec- 
ords of  the  American  Colonization  Society,  where,  of  many 
thousands  of  letters,  probably  not  a  dozen,  written  prior  to 
1846,  attempted  a  defence  of  the  principle  of  slavery. 

The  organization  of  the  Society  was  completed  January 
i,  1817,  when  Judge  Bushrod  Washington  was  elected 

7  Ibid.,  vol.  i,  pp.  199-200. 

8  Letters  of   American   Colonization   Society,   MS.,   G.   Smith  to 
Walter  Lourie,  Albany,  N.  Y.,  Dec.  31,  1834. 

9  Ibid.,  Geo.  Sheldon  to  Gurley,  Canton,  Ohio,  Aug.  2,  1836. 
"African  Repository,  vol.  i,  p.  89. 


363]       ORGANIZATION,  PURPOSE,  EARLY  YEARS         5! 

President,  the  following  being  elected  Vice-Presidents : 
William  H.  Crawford  of  Georgia ;  Henry  Clay  of  Kentucky ; 
William  Phillips  of  Massachusetts;  Col.  Henry  Rutgers  of 
New  York;  John  E.  Howard,  Samuel  Smith,  and  John  C. 
Herbert,  all  of  Maryland ;  John  Taylor  of  Caroline,  in  Vir- 
ginia ;  Gen.  Andrew  Jackson  of  Tennessee ;  Robert  Ralston 
of  Pennsylvania,  and  Richard  Rush,  of  the  same  State; 
General  John  Mason  of  the  District  of  Columbia,  and  Rev. 
Robert  Finley  of  New  Jersey.  The  foregoing,  with  E.  B. 
Caldwell,  Secretary,  W.  G.  D.  Worthington,  Recorder, 
David  English,  Treasurer,  and  Francis  Scott  Key,  Gen. 
Walter  Jones,  John  Laird,  Rev.  James  Laurie,  Rev.  Stephen 
B.  Balch,  Rev.  Obadiah  B.  Brown,  James  H.  Blake,  John 
Peter,  Edmund  J.  Lee,  William  Thornton,  Jacob  Hoffman 
and  Henry  Carroll  constituted  the  Board  of  Managers. 
On  the  list  of  first  contributors  to  the  efforts  of  the  Society 
appear  the  signatures,  among  others,  of  Henry  Clay,  John 
Randolph  of  Roanoke,  William  Thornton,  Daniel  Webster, 
William  Dudly  Diggs,  Samuel  J.  Mills,  Richard  Bland  Lee, 
John  Taylor  of  Caroline  and  Bushrod  Washington.11 

Within  a  fortnight  of  the  organization  of  the  Society,  a 
memorial  was  presented  to  both  Houses  of  Congress,  calling 
attention  to  the  condition  and  prospects  of  the  free  colored 
population,  calling  attention  also  to  the  fact  that,  in  order  to 
safeguard  themselves  against  what  might  prove  dire  conse- 
quences, important  slaveholding  States  had  adopted  meas- 
ures to  restrict  the  further  growth  of  the  evil,  by  the  enact- 
ment of  laws  prohibiting  emancipations  within  the  State. 
The  memorialists  consider  the  right  of  emancipating  slaves 
"  a  right  which  benevolent  or  conscientious  proprietors  had 
long  enjoyed  under  all  the  sanctions  of  positive  law,  and  of 
ancient  usage,"  and  suggest  as  a  more  satisfactory  solution 
of  the  problem,  that  adequate  provision  be  made  for  the 
establishment  of  such  a  colony  as  the  Society  later  estab- 
lished. The  subject  of  the  colonization  of  Africa  was  pre- 
sented in  its  varied  aspects :  as  a  movement  for  ridding  the 

11  Original  List  of  Subscribers,  MS. 


52  THE  AMERICAN    COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [364 

United  States  of  a  separate  caste  or  class,  dangerous  to  the 
peace  and  safety  of  the  country ;  as  an  important  factor  in 
the  elevation  of  the  free  negro,  who,  it  was  believed,  could 
never  rise  to  his  possibilities  in  the  United  States;  as  an 
instrument  for  the  spread  of  civilization  in  Africa,  and  as 
promising  much  as  a  missionary  enterprise.  Pickering,  for 
the  House  Committee  on  the  Slave  Trade,  reported  favor- 
ably, urging  that  the  free  negro,  when  colonized,  should  be 
sent  where  he  would  never  provoke  friction  with  the  whites. 
Africa  was  considered  the  most  desirable  place  for  the  reali- 
zation of  this  object.  The  committee  expressed  its  belief 
that  the  civilized  powers  should  engage  and  assent  to  "  the 
perfect  neutrality  of  the  colony."  It  was  believed  that 
arrangements  might  be  made,  whereby  the  colony  might  be 
incorporated  with  that  at  Sierra  Leone.  A  resolution,  not 
acted  on  at  that  session  of  Congress,  was  recommended, 
directing  that  the  United  States  open  negotiations  with  other 
powers  for  the  abolition  of  the  slave  trade,  and  with  Great 
Britain  for  the  reception  into  Sierra  Leone  of  "  such  of  the 
free  people  of  color  of  the  United  States  as,  with  their  own 
consent,  shall  be  carried  thither."  In  case  no  such  arrange- 
ment could  be  made,  it  was  recommended  that  the  United 
States  should  seek  to  obtain  from  Great  Britain  and  the 
other  maritime  powers  a  guarantee  of  "  permanent  neutral- 
ity for  the  formation  of  such  a  colony."12 

In  October,  a  committee  was  appointed  to  interview 
President  Monroe  who,  during  the  whole  term  of  his  presi- 
dency, actively  cooperated  with  the  Society.18  In  Novem- 
ber, Rev.  Samuel  J.  Mills  and  Ebenezer  Burgess  were 
appointed  the  Society's  first  agents  to  Africa.  They  were 
directed  to  go  by  way  of  England  and  secure  there  such 
information  as  they  could,  that  would  be  helpful  in  the  se- 
lection of  territory  favorable  for  the  proposed  colony. 

12  27th  Cong.,  3d  Sess.,  H.  Rept.,  no.  283,  pp.  208-213.  J-  P-  Ken- 
nedy's Report.  This  is  a  most  valuable  document  on  colonization 
and  the  slave  trade.  By  some,  it  was  considered  the  most  important 
House  Report  of  the  session. 

18  Journal  of  Board  of  Managers  of  American  Colonization  So- 
ciety, MS.,  October,  1817. 


365]  ORGANIZATION,  PURPOSE,  EARLY   YEARS  53 

From  there,  they  were  to  proceed  to  the  West  Coast  of 
Africa  for  the  purpose  of  exploration  and  of  ascertaining 
the  best  situation  for  the  establishment  of  such  a  colony  as 
the  Society  contemplated.  They  were  to  observe  the  cli- 
mate, soil,  etc.,  of  such  parts  of  the  coast  as  they  visited, 
"as  it  is  in  contemplation  to  turn  the  attention  of  the  new 
colonists  mostly  to  agriculture."14  On  the  return  voyage 
Mills  died. 

At  the  annual  meeting,  January  I,  1818,  President  Wash- 
ington reported  a  growing  interest  in  every  part  of  the 
Union  in  favor  of  the  Society;  also  a  respectable  subscrip- 
tion from  a  "  small  but  opulent  society  of  slave-holders  in 
Virginia."  Further,  it  was  stated : 

Should  it  [the  Society]  lead  as  we  may  fairly  hope  it  will,  to  the 
slow  but  gradual  abolition  of  slavery,  it  will  wipe  from  our  political 
institutions  the  only  blot  which  stains  them;  and  in  palliation  of 
which,  we  shall  not  be  at  liberty  to  plead  the  excuse  of  moral  neces- 
sity, until  we  have  honestly  exerted  all  the  means  which  we  possess 
for  its  extinction.16 

During  this  first  year,  also,  auxiliary  societies  had  been 
formed  in  Baltimore,  Philadelphia,  New  York,  Virginia, 
and  Ohio.16 

Already,  by  1819,  one  happy  result  of  the  Society's  efforts 
was  seen  in  an  act  passed  by  the  State  of  Georgia.  It  was 
an  act  providing  for  the  disposal  of  slaves  illegally  imported 
into  the  State.  Such  slaves,  if  captured,  were  to  be  consid- 
ered the  property  of  the  State  and  were  to  be  sold  at  auc- 
tion, provided  that,  in  case  the  Colonization  Society  agreed 
to  transport  such  negroes  to  such  foreign  colony  as  the  So- 
ciety might  have  established,  the  negroes,  after  payment  by 
the  Society  of  all  expenses  incurred  by  the  State  in  connec- 
tion with  them,  were  to  be  transferred  to  the  Society.17 
This  was  the  beginning  of  a  crusade  against  the  African 
slave-trade,  and  from  this  time  until  that  trade  had  ceased, 

14  Minutes  of  Board  of  Managers  of  American  Colonization  So- 
ciety, MS.,  Nov.  5,  1817. 

15  Origin,  Constitution,  and  Proceedings  of  American  Colonization 
Society,  MS.,  vol.  i,  pp.  20-23. 

18  Ibid.,  vol.  i,  pp.  23-30. 
17  Ibid.,  vol.  i,  pp.  65-74, 


54  THE  AMERICAN   COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [366 

the  Society's  existence  would  have  been  amply  justified  if 
it  had  accomplished  nothing  beyond  its  influence  against  that 
inhuman  traffic.  It  is  believed  that  Charles  Fenton  Mercer, 
"  the  Wilberf orce  of  America,"  was  inspired  by  his  interest 
in  African  colonization  to  wage,  in  Congress,  a  warfare 
against  the  African  slave  trade  such  as  was  waged  by  no 
other  American.  The  Anti-Slave-Trade  Act  of  1819  was 
the  outcome  of  a  memorial  from  the  Board  of  Managers  of 
the  Colonization  Society.18  In  the  annual  report  of  the 
Board  of  Managers,  1819,  the  efforts  of  the  managers  are 
stated  to  be  directed  to  "the  happiness  of  the  free  people  of 
colour  and  the  reduction  of  the  number  of  slaves  in 
America/'10 

In  January,  1819,  a  letter  from  the  Colonization  Society 
was  presented  in  the  House  of  Representatives.  The  ef- 
forts of  the  Society  in  sending  out  Mills  and  Burgess  were 
noted,  and  it  was  stated  that,  although  the  Society  owed  its 
origin  to  philanthropic  individuals,  its  purposes  could  not 
be  satisfactorily  realized  and  its  success  could  not  be  com- 
plete unless  it  had  the  support  of  the  Federal  government.20 
Probably  the  greatest  single  disappointment  the  Society 
ever  experienced  was  in  the  continued  refusal  of  the  Fed- 
eral government  to  appropriate  funds  for  the  carrying  out 
of  the  chief  purpose  of  the  Society;  the  transportation  and 
settlement  of  free  persons  of  color  on  the  west  coast  of 
Africa.  Year  after  year  memorials  were  presented;  year 
after  year  favorable  reports  were  read  from  House  com- 
mittees to  which  the  memorials  were  referred;  and  year 
after  year  Congress  refused  to  make  an  appropriation. 
There  can  be  no  doubt  that  when  the  Society  was  formed,  it 
looked  to  the  Federal  government  for  aid  in  its  under- 
taking.21 

This  disposition  to  leave  the  Society  to  work  out  its  own 
program  and  collect,  as  best  it  could,  the  funds  that  were 

18  Ibid.,  vol.  i,  p.  88. 

19  Ibid.,  vol.  i,  pp.  65-74. 

20  27th  Cong.,  3d  Sess.,  H.  Rept.  no.  283,  pp.  223-225. 

21  Origin,  Constitution,  and  Proceedings  of  American  Coloniza- 
tion Society,  MS.    See  Original  Constitution. 


367]  ORGANIZATION,  PURPOSE,  EARLY   YEARS  $5 

necessary,  was  not  shared  by  President  Monroe.  When  the 
Anti-Slave-Trade  Act  of  1819  was  passed,  he  construed  it 
liberally  and,  in  cooperation  with  the  managers  of  the  Colo- 
nization Society,  sent  out  Agents  of  the  United  States  to 
select  on  the  west  African  coast  a  territory  on  which  recap- 
tured Africans  might  be  landed  and  cared  for  by  the  gov- 
ernment.22 The  first  material  result  of  this  cooperation 
was  the  chartering,  in  1820,  of  the  Elizabeth  by  the  govern- 
ment, and  her  departure  from  New  York  with  Rev.  Samuel 
Bacon  and  John  P.  Bankson,  government  agents,  Samuel  C. 
Crozer,  agent  for  the  Colonization  Society,  and  eighty-odd 
free  negroes.  Going  by  way  of  Sierra  Leone,  the  company 
landed  on  Sherbro  Island  where,  by  the  first  of  June,  the 
three  agents  and  twenty-four  of  the  settlers  had  died.23 

So  much  has  been  said  of  the  unhealthfulness  of  the 
territory  to  which  the  Society's  first  negroes  were  sent, 
that  it  will  be  fitting  here  to  record  the  facts  as  they  were 
presented  by  the  colonial  agents.  As  years  added  to  the 
experience  of  those  who  directed  the  settlement,  it  was 
observed  that  the  cases  of  African  fever  through  which 
most  of  the  immigrants  passed  were  less  frequent  and 
less  violent  among  those  who  arrived  during  the  dry  than 
among  those  who  arrived  during  the  rainy  season.  But  this 
lesson  had  to  be  learned  and,  although  the  Abolitionists  of 
the  Garrisonian  school  and  their  apologists  have  depicted  in 
glowing  terms  the  wretchedness  of  the  free  negro,  "expa- 
triated" and  sent  off,  out  of  the  way,  to  die  of  African 
fever,  it  is  yet  true  that  if  the  number  of  deaths  among  the 
Liberian  colonists  be  compared  with  the  number  of  deaths 
among  the  settlers  of  either  Virginia  or  Plymouth,  the  com- 
parison is  highly  favorable  to  the  Liberians  and  the  Coloni- 
zation Society,  and  this  notwithstanding  the  fact  that  the 
African  colonists  as  a  class  were  imprudent  in  observing 
even  the  essentials  of  personal  hygiene.24  They  insisted  on 
eating,  when  they  should  have  abstained  from  food.  They 

22  27th  Cong.,  3d  Sess.,  H.  Kept.  no.  283,  p.  2. 

23  Lugenbeel. 

"African  Repository,  vol.  xv,  p.  306. 


$6  THE  AMERICAN    COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [368 

exposed  themselves  needlessly  and  carelessly  and,  in  spite 
of  the  most  earnest  efforts  on  the  part  of  the  Society  and 
its  physicians  in  the  colony,  the  death-rate  figures  were 
eagerly  used  to  stir  up  opposition  among  the  New  Eng- 
landers. 

In  1832  the  Board  of  Managers  went  carefully  into  a  con- 
sideration of  the  actual  number  of  deaths,  the  causes  of 
death,  and  the  possibility  of  decreasing  materially  the  death- 
rate.    A  committee  appointed  for  that  purpose  reported 
that  since  1820,  twenty-two  expeditions  had  gone  out  from 
the  United  States  to  Liberia.     On  the  first  eighteen  of  these, 
1487  emigrants  had  been  transported.     Of  these,  two  hun^ 
dred  and  thirty  had  died  from  diseases  of  acclimation,  from 
fever  and   diseases  consequent  upon  it.     The  conclusion 
reached  was  that  the  three  most  fruitful  causes  of  death 
were,  in  descending  order :  ( I )  the  transportation  to  Africa 
of  persons  who  had  become  accustomed  to  the  high  or 
mountainous  country  in  the  United  States,  (2)  the  settle- 
ment of  immigrants  too  close  to  the  coast  and  in  the  heart 
of  the  malarial  district,  (3)  the  arrival  of  immigrants  at  the 
wrong  time  of  the  year.    While,  of  those  persons  who  left 
the  high,  and  non-malarial  sections  of  the  United  States, 
one  out  of  every  two  and  one-fourth  died ;  of  those  who  left 
the  malarial  sections  of  the  United  States,  only  one  out  of 
every  twenty-seven  died.     Of  those  landed  at  Monrovia,  a 
settlement  in  the  malarial  section,  one  out  of  every  five  died ; 
while,  of  those  landed  at  Caldwell,  further  from  the  coast 
and  having  a  greater  elevation,  one  in  every  fourteen  died. 
Of  those  transported  to  Liberia  during  the  rainy  season,  one 
out  of  every  four  and  one-third  died;  while,  of  those  trans- 
ported during  the  dry  season,  only  one  out  of  every  six  and 
two-thirds  died.25 

Thereafter,  the  Society  used  every  reasonable  precaution 
within  its  power  to  prevent  sickness,  to  care  for  those  who 
were  sick,  and  to  cut  down  the  death-rate— and  with  success. 

26  Minutes  Board  of  Managers  of  American  Colonization  Society, 
MS.,  May  7,  1832,  vol.  ii,  p.  273  ff. 


369]  ORGANIZATION,  PURPOSE,  EARLY   YEARS  5/ 

But  there  can  be  no  doubt  that  the  climate  was  much  more 
severe  in  its  effects  upon  the  health  of  the  white  man  than 
upon  that  of  the  black.  Indeed,  every  white  agent  who 
went  out,  from  the  first  expedition  until  the  independence 
of  the  Republic  of  Liberia  was  declared,  took  his  life  in  his 
hands  and  knew  very  well  that  the  odds  were  greatly  against 
not  only  his  health,  but  his  life.  Mills,  Bacon,  Crozer, 
Bankson,  Andrews,  Winns  and  his  wife,  Randall,  Anderson, 
Skinner  and  his  wife,  Ashmun  and  his  wife,  Buchanan — 
heroes  and  heroines  these — and  Ashmun  and  Buchanan 
the  greatest  of  them.  Men  and  women  who,  like  these,  lay 
down  their  lives  voluntarily  upon  the  altar  of  service,  are 
not  to  be  charged  with  selfishness  or  the  desire  to  perpetuate 
a  system  against  which  they  spoke  and  labored  eloquently. 

The  sending  of  expeditions  and  the  sustenance  of  emi- 
grants required  funds.  How  were  the  finances  to  be  pro- 
vided and  the  enthusiasm  spread  ?  The  President  had  gone 
as  far  as  he  could,  in  keeping  with  the  law  of  1819,  in  coop- 
eration with  the  Society.  By  that  law,  his  efforts  were 
confined  to  the  suppression  of  the  slave-trade.  No  direct 
appropriation  could  be  secured  from  Congress.  The  result 
was  that  for  many  years,  indeed,  during  the  whole  period 
covered  in  this  study,  the  important  sources  of  revenue 
were:  (i)  a  national  system  of  agencies,  (2)  receipts  from 
auxiliary  societies,  (3)  bequests  and  legacies,  (4)  State 
appropriations,  (5)  collections  taken  by  ministers  in  churches 
on  the  Fourth  of  July  each  year. 

As  early  as  March,  1819,  the  Managers  appointed  thir- 
teen agents  whose  duty  it  was  to  collect  funds  and  arouse 
interest  throughout  the  Union.  Among  these  were  General 
Walter  Jones,  C.  F.  Mercer,  William  H.  Fitzhugh,  and 
Francis  Scott  Key.  But  the  first  important  general  agent 
of  the  Society  was  Rev.  William  Meade.  The  origin  of  the 
agency  is  interesting.  William  H.  Crawford,  who  was  pre- 
siding at  a  meeting  of  the  Managers,  in  April,  1819,  called 
attention  to  an  advertisement  he  had  found  in  a  Georgia 
newspaper.  Thirty  or  forty  negroes  had  been  illegally  im- 


58  THE  AMERICAN   COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [370 

ported  into  the  State.  The  law  of  the  State  required  that 
they  should  be  sold  at  auction,  unless,  by  a  provision  already 
referred  to,  they  could  be  taken  over  by  the  Colonization 
Society,  and  transported  to  Africa.  Meade  was  at  once 
sent  to  Georgia  to  make  an  effort  to  save  the  negroes  from 
slavery. 

In  May,  Meade  reported  that  the  Governor  had  agreed 
to  postpone  the  sale  and  "afforded  me  an  opportunity  of 
seeking  among  the  humane  and  generous  of  this  southern 
country,  the  means  of  their  redemption."26  In  June  he  re- 
ported that  arrangements  had  been  made,  by  which  the 
negroes  were  to  be  turned  over  to  the  Society.  "  Some  who 
had  but  little  hope  of  our  general  enterprize  declared  their 
willingness  to  contribute  for  the  ransome  of  these;  and  a 
few  who  intended  to  have  become  the  purchasers  at  this 
sale,  expressed  a  pleasure  at  the  thought  of  their  restora- 
tion to  Africa,  and  proved  their  sincerity  by  uniting  with 
the  Society  at  Milledgeville."  Under  the  direction  of  the 
most  prominent  citizens  of  the  State,  he  had  formed  three 
auxiliary  societies.  At  Augusta  and  Savannah  he  found 
similar  good  feeling  toward  the  Society.  Of  the  negroes 
at  Charleston  he  says:  "their  attendance  in  the  church 
where  I  was  invited  to  officiate,  (and  it  was  the  same,  I  was 
told,  in  all  the  others,)  was  truly  grateful  to  the  soul  of  the 
Christian.  The  aisles  and  other  places  in  the  church  set 
apart  for  them,  were  filled  with  young  and  old,  decently 
dressed  and  many  of  them  having  their  prayer  books,  and 
joining  in  all  the  responses  of  the  church.  I  must  also  beg 
leave  to  add  a  general  remark  concerning  the  whole  South- 
ern country,  in  which  I  am  justified  by  the  repeated  assur- 
ances of  the  most  pious  and  benevolent  that  the  condition 
of  the  negroes  is  greatly  ameliorated  in  every  respect.  As 
to  food,  raiment,  houses,  labour,  and  correction,  there  is 
yearly  less  and  less  over  which  religion  and  humanity  must 
lament."  At  Georgetown  he  saw  "  eight  or  ten  of  the  most 

*6  Minutes  Board  of  Managers  of  American  Colonization  Society, 
MS.,  April  7,  1819;  May  4,  1819. 


3/l]  ORGANIZATION,  PURPOSE,  EARLY  YEARS  59 

wealthy  and  influential,  and  obtained  assurances  of  their 
cordial  co-operation."  At  Fayetteville  "all  the  citizens 
prepared  for  co-operation.  I  had  only  to  go  to  their  houses 
and  take  down  their  names." 

At  Raleigh  he  found  "the  same  unanimity  of  sentiment. 
The  supreme  court  being  in  session,  many  of  the  judges  and 
lawyers  were  collected  from  the  different  parts  of  the  State, 
who  cordially  joined  in  the  Society,  and  testified  to  the  gen- 
eral prevalence  of  good  will  to  it  throughout  the  State.  At 
a  meeting  for  forming  a  constitution,  the  highest  talents, 
authorities,  and  wealth  of  the  State  were  present,  and  unani- 
mously sanctioned  the  measure."  From  Raleigh,  he  went 
to  Chapel  Hill,  the  seat  of  the  State  University.  It  was 
commencement  time,  and  ministers,  trustees,  and  other  per- 
sons of  influence  were  assembled.  "  I  was  happy  to  find 
the  same  feeling  here,  and  that  a  small  -society  had  already 
been  formed."  For  his  agency  as  a  whole,  he  reported  six 
organized,  and  ten  or  twelve  prospective,  societies.  He  had 
secured,  in  about  two  months  time,  subscriptions  amounting 
to  between  seven  and  eight  thousand  dollars.  He  reported 
that  his  success  in  raising  funds  would  have  been  greater, 
but  for  the  fact  that  "  the  pecuniary  distress  is,  by  universal 
consent,  greater  than  ever  was  known.  ...  I  was  told  a 
hundred  times  that  no  other  cause  but  this  would  elicit  any- 
thing." Of  the  general  feeling  in  regard  to  the  Society,  he 
reported  "a  conviction  that  unless  a  great  alteration  takes 
place ;  or  I  have  been  misinformed,  it  will  meet  with  a  lib- 
eral support."27  During  the  early  years  of  the  Society,  Rev. 
William  Meade  also  undertook  a  local  agency  in  his  own 
county  in  the  Valley  of  Virginia.  He  secured  subscriptions 
amounting  to  almost  seven  thousand  dollars  there,  his  own 
near  relatives  contributing,  with  himself,  seventeen  hun- 
dred dollars.28 

In  1825  William  H.  Fitzhugh,  of  Virginia,  was  appointed 
to  go  through  the  Middle  Atlantic  and  New  England  States 

27  Ibid.,  Report  of  Meade,  June  21,  1819. 
"African  Repository,  vol.  i,  pp.  146-147. 


6O  THE  AMERICAN    COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [3/2 

in  the  interests  of  the  Society.  Theodore  Frelinghuysen, 
of  New  Jersey,  received  an  appointment  in  1828,  as  did 
also  Rev.  Leonard  Bacon,  of  Connecticut.29  In  1830,  the 
Managers  resolved  to  appoint  a  permanent  agent  for  the 
New  England  States,  "who  by  correspondence,  the  estab- 
lishment of  auxiliary  societies,  and  an  attendance  upon  the 
Legislatures  of  those  States  shall  awaken  a  more  general 
and  active  interest  in  the  object  and  augment  the  funds  of 
the  Society."  Whenever  desirable  agents  could  be  obtained 
general  agencies  were  created  for  the  lower  Middle  States, 
the  upper  Middle  States,  the  New  England  States,  the 
Western  States,  the  Southern  States,  and  the  Southwestern 
States.  During  the  years  1838  to  1845  these  agencies  were 
by  far  the  most  important  source  of  revenue  that  the  So- 
ciety had. 

Thousands  of  dollars  were  annually  turned  over  to  the 
funds  of  the  parent  Society  by  the  various  State  and  county 
societies.  The  organization  toward  which  the  Society 
worked,  in  its  earlier  years,  was,  (i)  the  parent  organiza- 
tion, (2)  a  State  auxiliary  society  in  every  State  of  the 
Union,  (3)  societies  auxiliary  to  the  State  societies,  in  every 
county  of  every  State.  There  was  a  time  when  the  number 
of  auxiliary  societies  was  about  one  hundred  and  fifty.80 

Of  these,  special  mention  should  be  made  of  the  Vermont 
Society,  over  which  the  venerable  Elijah  Paine  presided  for 
many  years ;  the  Massachusetts  Society,  among  whose  fore- 
most members  were  Joseph  Tracy  and  Simon  Greenleaf; 
the  Connecticut  Society,  with  Leonard  Bacon,  Roger  M. 
Sherman  and  Governor  Tomlinson;81  the  New  York  So- 
ciety, which  for  years  was  favored  with  the  services  of  Dr. 
Alexander  Proudfit  and  President  Duer  of  Columbia,  and 
which  received  liberal  support  from  Benjamin  F.  Butler 
and,  until  about  1835,  from  the  philanthropist,  Gerrit 

29  Board  of  Managers  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS., 
Sept.  5,  1828. 

80  For  lists  of  the  auxiliary  societies  see  appendices  to  the  annual 
reports  of  the  American  Colonization  Society. 

81  African  Repository,  vol.  v,  p.  93. 


373]  ORGANIZATION,  PURPOSE,  EARLY   YEARS  6 1 

Smith ;  the  New  Jersey  Society,  with  Judge  Halsey  a  lead- 
ing spirit ;  the  Young  Men's  Society  of  Philadelphia,  which 
at  times  was  almost  completely  under  the  dominance  of 
that  quaint,  queer,  irrepressible  Quaker,  Elliot  Cresson,  who 
whether  at  home,  or  in  England,  or  in  Mississippi,  or  in 
Vermont,  never  failed  to  impress  his  hearers  with  his  un- 
tiring energy,  and  oftentimes  with  his  utter  disagreement 
with  Garrison  as  to  the  method  of  ridding  the  land  of 
slavery,  although  he  was  as  anxious  as  Garrison  to  get  rid 
of  the  whole  system;  the  Maryland  Society,  that  counted 
among  its  leaders  Key,  C.  C.  Harper,  John  E.  Howard,  and 
J.  H.  B.  Latrobe ;  the  Virginia  Society,  whose  President  in 
1833  was  John  Marshall,  and  among  whose  twelve  Vice- 
Presidents  were  John  Tyler,  James  Madison,  James  Pleas- 
ants,  Hugh  Nelson,  William  H.  Broadnax,  William  Max- 
well, and  Abel  P.  Upshur;32  the  Loudpun  County  (Vir- 
ginia) Society,  one  of  whose  Presidents  was  James  Monroe; 
the  Petersburg  (Virginia)  Society,  in  which  John  Early, 
later  a  bishop  in  the  Southern  Methodist  Church,  was  for 
years  a  most  active  member;  also  the  Societies  of  Ken- 
tucky, Ohio,  Louisiana,  and  Mississippi,  the  last  two  of 
which,  for  some  years,  exerted  an  influence  that  brought 
about  the  liberation  of  hundreds  of  slaves,  that  established 
a  separate  settlement  at  Sinoe  in  the  Liberian  country,  and 
counted  among  their  members  and  leaders,  John  Ker,  John 
McDonogh,  William  Winans,  and  Zebulun  Butler.  In 
1824  there  were  only  twenty  auxiliary  societies ;  two  years 
later  there  were  forty-six.  From  this  time  the  number  grew 
rapidly.33  By  1838,  it  seems,  auxiliary  societies  had  been 
organized  in  every  State  and  Territory  in  the  Union,  except 
Rhode  Island,  South  Carolina,  Arkansas,  and  Michigan.84 

Another  source  of  revenue  was  the  subscription  of  large 
sums  by  philanthropists  throughout  the  Union.  Mercer 
was  one  of  the  earliest  contributors  of  this  class.  About 
1821  he  pledged  himself  to  be  responsible  for  the  collection 

82  Ibid.,  vol.  ix,  pp.  24-25. 
88  Ibid.,  vol.  i,  p.  347. 
84  Ibid.,  vol.  xiv,  p.  100. 


62  THE   AMERICAN   COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [3/4 

of  $5000,  with  which  to  begin  the  active  operations  of  the 
Society,  he  to  be  personally  liable  for  that  amount  if  he 
failed  to  secure  it  by  solicitation.35  Gerrit  Smith,  later  Abo- 
litionist, proposed,  in  1828,  that  friends  of  the  Society  con- 
tribute $100  per  year  for  ten  years.  The  plan  became  well 
known  as  the  Gerrit  Smith  plan.  Of  $54,000  contributed 
on  this  plan,  the  New  England  States  gave  $9000,  New  York, 
Pennsylvania,  New  Jersey  and  Delaware  $14,000,  Maryland 
and  the  District  of  Columbia,  $4000 ;  the  South  $26,000,  and 
the  Northwest  $iooo.36  One  of  the  contributors  on  this 
plan  was  Gerrit  Smith ;  another,  Mathew  Carey,  also  Theo- 
dore Frelinghuysen,  John  McDonogh  of  New  Orleans,  John 
H.  Cocke  of  Virginia,  and  Courtlandt  Van  Rensaelaer  of 
New  York.  J.  H.  McClure,  of  Kentucky,  gave  $1000  per 
year  for  ten  years.  George  Hargraves  of  Georgia,  and 
John  Marshall  of  Virginia  gave  $500  each.37  Gerrit  Smith 
contributed,  besides  his  contribution  on  the  Gerrit  Smith 
plan,  $5000,  when  the  Society  reached  a  period  of  extreme 
need.88  Judge  Workman  of  New  Orleans  left,  by  will,  to 
the  Society  $10,000.  Colonel  Rutgers  of  New  York  left 
$1000.  "Two  Friends  "  in  Georgia  left  $500  each.89  Childers 
of  Mississippi  left  a  sum  which  was  estimated  to  be  about 
$30,000.*°  James  Madison  left  $2000  and  also  the  proceeds 
from  the  sale  of  a  grist  mill  and  lot.41  Daniel  Waldo  and 
his  wife  of  Boston  gave  $24,000  in  i845.42 

Soon  after  the  Southampton  Insurrection  in  1831,  and 
due  in  large  measure  to  the  alarm  that  was  excited  by  it,  the 
Maryland  Legislature  provided  for  an  appropriation  total- 

86  Fragment  in  Gurley*s  handwriting,  MS.,  in  which  is  copied  a 
letter  from  C.  F.  Mercer. 

86  Life  Members,  MS. 

87  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Hargraves  to 
Treasurer,  Augusta,  Ga.,  June  9,  1833;  African  Repository,  vol.  ix, 
P.  364. 

88  African  Repository,  vol.  ix,  p.  364. 

89  Ibid.,  vol.  viii,  p.  366. 

40  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Gurley  to  P.  R. 
Fendall,  July  16,  1836. 

"African  Repository,  vol.  xii,  p.  237. 

42  Letters  to  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Joseph  Tracy 
to  McLain,  Boston,  Sept  5,  1845. 


3/S]      ORGANIZATION,  PURPOSE,  EARLY  YEARS        63 

ing  $200,000,  payable  in  instalments  each  year.  Because 
of  the  independent  action  of  the  Maryland  Society,  the  par- 
ent organization  was  deprived  of  this  source  of  revenue/8 
At  about  the  same  time,  the  Virginia  Legislature  made  an 
appropriation  of  $90,000,  though  certain  restrictions  as  to 
its  application  made  it  almost  useless  for  the  purposes  of 
the  Society.4*  In  1850  the  Legislature  of  the  same  State 
appropriated  $30,000  per  year  for  five  years,  on  condition 
that  the  negroes  for  whose  transportation  the  fund  was  to 
provide  were  free  at  the  time  of  the  passage  of  the  act,  were 
residents  of  Virginia,  and  had  already  been  transported 
when  application  was  made  for  the  payment  of  the  amount 
appropriated  for  such  transportation.45  In  addition  to  these 
sources  of  revenue  John  McDonogh,  by  will,  left  to  the  So- 
ciety $25,000  annually,46  and  David  Hunt  of  Mississippi  left 
to  it  $45,ooo.47 

The  fifth  source  of  revenue,  and  it  was  much  more  than 
a  mere  source  of  revenue,  was  the  annual  Fourth  of  July 
collection  taken  up  in  churches  in  almost  every  part  of  the 
Union.  In  these  days,  when  a  most  important  new  light 
has  been  thrown  upon  the  forces  that  have  cooperated  in 
the  making  of  history;  when,  particularly  in  the  study  of 
that  generation  from  1830  to  1860 — a  time  pregnant  with 
problems  and  with  possibilities,  and  with  historical  inter- 
pretations— the  economic  interpretation  is  monopolizing  in- 
terest, it  has  become  habitual  with  students  of  history  to 
speak  and  write  in  terms  of  cotton  production,  the  cotton 
gin,  the  expanding  Southwest,  and  so  on.  There  is  very 
much  truth  in  this  from  the  point  of  view  of  the  South. 
But,  from  the  point  of  view  of  the  North,  that  busy  decade 
from  1835  to  1845  was  tne  battleground  between  public 

43  African  Repository,  vol.  viii,  p.  61. 

44  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  F.  Knight  to  Dr.  A. 
Cummings,  vol.  iii,  no.  738,  Aug.  17,  1840. 

46  Journal  of  Executive  Committee  of  American  Colonization  So- 
ciety, 1845-54,  March  16,  1850,  pp.  139-141. 

48  Journal  of  Board  of  Directors  of  American  Colonization  So- 
ciety, MS.,  Jan.  23,  1851,  vol.  iv,  pp.  90-91. 

4T  Ibid.,  voL  iv,  p.  271. 


64  THE  AMERICAN    COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [376 

opinion,  so-called,  and  that  opinion  moulded  by  the  active 
and  lay  ministry,  meaning  by  the  lay  ministry  that  body  of 
educational  and  philanthropic  men  who,  from  lecture  room 
or  counting  house,  cooperated  with  the  Christian  ministry 
in  forming  a  distinctly  church  sentiment.  At  the  begin- 
ning of  that  decade  the  ministry  was  leading  public  senti- 
ment; at  the  end  of  it  public  sentiment  was  leading  the 
ministry.  This  is  altogether  obvious  from  the  correspond- 
ence preserved  by  the  Society. 

From  the  organization  of  the  Society  in  1817  to  the  early 
thirties,  the  ministry  all  over  New  England  cooperated 
splendidly  with  the  Colonization  managers,  preached  annual 
sermons  on  Colonization,  on  or  near  the  Fourth  of  July, 
and  contributed  to  the  Washington  office  annually  thou- 
sands of  dollars.  At  their  general  conferences  and  asso- 
ciations they  passed  with  great  unanimity  resolutions  com- 
mendatory of  the  Society,  and  urged  a  continuance  of  the 
July  sermons  and  collections.  Beginning  with  the  thirties, 
church  doors  in  New  England  and  in  many  parts  of  the 
West  were  closed  to  Colonization  lecturers  and  agents,  and 
the  reason  given,  in  scores  of  cases,  was  not  an  objection 
of  the  minister  himself,  but  his  fear  that  his  membership 
would  be  displeased  if  he  allowed  the  use  of  his  pulpit  to 
Colonizationist  lecturers.  From  1817  to  1830  cooperation 
and  collections  from  the  pew  in  the  New  England  States 
were  important  contributions  to  the  early  success  of  the 
enterprise. 

Among  the  contributors  to  the  Colonization  treasury  must 
be  mentioned  also  the  Society  of  Friends,  particularly  the 
Friends  of  North  Carolina  who,  though  comparatively  poor, 
contributed  very  liberally  to  the  transportation  of  free  ne- 
groes. As  early  as  1820,  they  paid  over  to  the  Society 
eight  hundred  dollars.48  In  1827  they  again  contributed 
the  same  amount.49  Between  1825  and  1830,  Masonic 

"Journal  of  Board  of  Managers  of  American  Colonization  ?o- 
ciety,  MS.,  May  30,  1820. 

49  African  Repository,  vol.  ii,  p.  351 ;  Journal  of  Board  of  Mana- 
gers of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Feb.  12,  1827. 


377]  ORGANIZATION,  PURPOSE,  EARLY   YEARS  65 

Lodge  chapters  in  Maryland,  Pennsylvania,  Maine,  Massa- 
chusetts, Columbus  and  Woodville,  Mississippi,  also  sent  in 
contributions.50 

But  to  return  to  our  narrative  of  the  Society's  operations. 
In  1820,  the  fifteen  Vice-Presidents  were  equally  divided 
between  the  States  south  of  the  border  States,  the  border 
States,  and  the  States  north  of  those  States,  five  being 
elected  from  Georgia,  Tennessee,  and  Virginia;  five  from 
Kentucky,  the  District  of  Columbia,  and  Maryland,  and  five 
from  Pennsylvania,  New  Jersey,  New  York,  and  Massachu- 
setts.51 Of  the  funds  received  by  the  Society  by  the  time 
the  Elizabeth  sailed  for  Africa,  out  of  a  total  of  $14,031.50, 
the  States  north  of  the  border  States  had  contributed 
$2664.67,  the  District  of  Columbia  and  Maryland  had  con- 
tributed $8466.58,  and  the  States  south  of  the  border 
States  had  contributed  $2900.25. 52  If  those  who  already 
believed  that  the  Society  was  an  organization  gotten  up  by 
slaveholders  for  the  purpose  of  getting  rid  of  the  free  ne- 
gro, and  thereby  increasing  the  value  of  the  slaves  that  they 
desired  to  sell  further  South,  had  taken  the  trouble  to  think 
upon  these  figures,  they  would  have  seen  that  Virginia,  the 
State,  above  all  others,  to  which  their  views  might  have  been 
expected  to  apply,  was  sending  in  contributions  that  were 
just  about  equal  to  those  that  came  from  the  States  in 
which  slavery  had  already  been  abolished;  and  that  the 
movement  was  a  national,  not  a  sectional  one,  although  its 
vital  energy  undoubtedly  did  come  from  the  middle-State 
section. 

Even  before  the  Elizabeth  sailed,  the  managers  went  care- 
fully into  the  question  of  the  practicability  of  their  scheme. 
They  considered  the  "marrow"  of  the  arguments  against 
colonization  to  be  whether  or  not  the  colony  proposed  could 
receive  and  subsist,  or  the  Society  transport,  all  the  free 

50  African  Repository,  vol.  ii,  p.  353 ;  Letters  of  American  Coloni- 
zation Society,  Apr.  21,  1827,  May  21,  1827,  May  24,  1827. 

81  Origin,  Constitution,  and  Proceedings  of  American  Coloniza- 
zation  Society,  MS.*  vol.  i,  pp.  118-119. 

62  Ibid.,  vol.  i,  pp.  150-151. 


66  THE  AMERICAN    COLONIZATION   SOCIETY 

negroes  from  the  United  States.  They  realized  that  the 
colony  could  not  receive,  in  any  one  year,  more  immigrants 
than  could  be  provided  for  by  the  annual  surplus  products 
of  the  colony,  including  importations.  They  doubted  whether 
the  Society,  unaided  by  the  resources  of  the  State  or  Fed- 
eral governments,  could  transport  the  annual  increase  in 
the  free  negro  population,  about  5000.  But  with  such  gov- 
ernmental aid,  they  were  sure  of  the  success  of  their  under- 
taking. At  any  rate,  they  said,  whether  accompanied  by 
complete  or  only  partial  success,  the  movement  could  not 
but  have  the  most  salutary  results.  As  was  said  at  the 
time: 

Although  it  is  believed,  and  is,  indeed,  too  obvious  to  require  proof, 
that  the  colonization  of  the  free  people  of  colour,  alone,  would  not 
only  tend  to  civilise  Africa;  to  abolish  the  slave  trade;  and  greatly 
to  advance  their  own  happiness;  but  to  promote  that,  also,  of  the 
other  classes  of  society,  the  proprietors  and  their  slaves,  yet  the 
hope  of  the  gradual  and  utter  abolition  of  slavery,  in  a  manner  con- 
sistent with  the  rights,  interests,  and  happiness  of  society,  ought 
never  to  be  abandoned.58 

If  Ohio,  with  one  crop  only  a  year,  could  add  on  an  aver- 
age 26,000  a  year  to  her  population,  could  not  the  west  coast 
of  Africa,  with  two  crops  a  year  and  a  perpetual  summer, 
sustain  an  average  immigration  of  5000  from  the  United 
States?  Indeed,  ought  it  not  to  be  able  to  sustain  the 
whole  of  the  annual  increase  of  the  negro  population  of  the 
United  States,  free  and  slave,  which  amounted  to  40,000? 
If  only  the  movement  would  receive  cordial  support,  be- 
tween America  and  Africa  an  interchange  of  useful  articles 
would  take  the  place  of  trade  in  human  beings,  and 

new  forms  of  Government,  modelled  after  those  which  constitute 
the  pride  and  boast  of  America,  will  attest  the  extent  of  their  obli- 
gations to  their  former  masters,  and  myriads  of  freemen,  while  they 
course  the  margin  of  the  Gambia,  the  Senegal,  the  Congo,  and  the 
Niger,  will  sing,  in  the  language  which  records  the  constitution, 
laws,  and  history  of  America,  hymns  of  praise  to  the  common  parent 
of  man.5* 

But  these  high  hopes  were  disturbed,  and  it  was  a  gloomy 
day  among  the  Managers  when,  in  October,  1820,  they  dis- 

88  Ibid.,  vol.  i,  pp.  106-107. 
"Ibid.,  vol.  i,  pp.  107-115. 


379]  ORGANIZATION,  PURPOSE,  EARLY   YEARS  6/ 

cussed  the  prospects  for  colonization  in  the  light  of  the  dis- 
tressing news  that  had  come  of  the  large  number  of  deaths 
among  the  emigrants  carried  over  by  the  Elizabeth.  If 
there  was  much  likelihood  that  these  conditions  would  con- 
tinue, they  had  no  doubt  that  their  efforts  on  the  west  coast 
of  Africa  ought  to  be  given  up  without  delay.  But  the  ex- 
periment had  not  been  made  under  favorable  conditions. 
The  vessel  had  landed  during  the  unhealthful,  rainy  season. 
The  landing  and  settlement  had  been  made  at  a  most  unde- 
sirable location.  Diseases  had  been  contracted  on  the  vessel 
during  the  voyage.  Besides,  there  were  many  applicants 
who  were  not  only  ready  but  anxious  to  go.  The  decision 
was  that  they  must  continue  the  experiment.65 

Nothing  daunted,  therefore,  by  reports  from  the  first  ex- 
pedition,  the  United  States  Government  chartered  the  Nau- 
tilus, and  she  sailed  from  Norfolk  early  in  1821,  and  to- 
wards the  latter  part  of  March,  the  same  year,  the  U.  S. 
Schooner  Augusta  sailed.  In  the  Nautilus  went  about 
thirty  emigrants  who,  with  a  number  of  those  who  had  been 
transported  in  the  Elizabeth,  were  received  into  Sierra 
Leone.  With  these  two  expeditions  went  Messrs.  Andrews, 
Winn,  Bacon,  Wittberger,  and  Mrs.  Winn,  agents  for  the 
Government  and  the  Society.  By  the  beginning  of  autumn, 
Andrews  and  Mr.  and  Mrs.  Winn  had  died.66 

Late  in  1821  Dr.  Eli  Ayres,  as  principal  agent  for  the  So- 
ciety, arrived  at  Sierra  Leone,  and  Captain  R.  F.  Stockton 
arrived  in  the  U.  S.  Schooner  Alligator.  December  n, 
Ayres  and  Stockton  anchored  off  Cape  Mesurado,  or  Mont- 
serado,  and  in  exchange  for  gunpowder,  tobacco,  muskets, 
iron  pots,  beads,  looking-glasses,  pipes,  cotton,  etc.,  secured 
a  title  deed  to  a  valuable  tract  of  land  which  was  the  nucleus 
of  what  is  now  the  Republic  of  Liberia.57  It  seems  that  the 

65  Journal  of  Board  of  Managers  of  American  Colonization  So- 
ciety, MS.,  October  16,  1820;  Origin,  Constitution  and  Proceedings 
of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  vol.  i,  pp.  131-149. 

66  Lugenbeel ;  African  Repository,  vol.  i,  pp.  3-4 ;  Origin,  Consti- 
tution, and  Proceedings  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  vol. 
i,  pp.  168-194. 

67  Lugenbeel. 


68  THE   AMERICAN    COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [380 

land  was  never  ceded  either  to  the  United  States  Govern- 
ment or  to  the  Colonization  Society.  It  was  ceded  to  Cap- 
tain Stockton  and  Dr.  Ayres  "  to  have  and  to  hold  the  said 
premises  for  the  use  of  these  said  [negroes]  citizens  of 
America."58  The  territory  was  a  trust,  and  was  from  the 
first  so  considered  by  the  Managers  of  the  Society.  From 
the  first,  they  looked  to  the  time  when  the  colony  they 
should  plant  would  be  able  to  stand  alone,  a  model  republic 
for  the  African  to  admire  and,  perhaps  some  day,  imitate. 
Ayres  then  returned  to  Sierra  Leone  and  prepared  to  plant 
the  emigrants  on  the  newly  ceded  territory.  By  April, 
1822,  this  had  been  done.59  At  the  beginning  of  summer 
Dr.  Ayres  left  Africa  for  America,  and  put  one  of  the  colo- 
nists, Elijah  Johnson,  in  charge  of  the  settlement. 

In  August  of  this  year,  the  brig  Strong  arrived  from  Bal- 
timore with  immigrants,  a  cargo  of  provisions,  and  Jehudi 
Ashmun,  a  name  that  must  ever  remain  first  in  importance 
among  the  early  white  men  who  went  to  Africa  to  help 
establish  the  Society's  colony.  An  indiscretion  on  the  part 
of  the  colonists  who  had  settled  at  Montserado,  arising  from 
a  wrong  interpretation  of  some  of  the  acts  of  the  native 
tribes,  and  the  inability  of  the  natives  to  appreciate  fully 
their  obligation  to  respect  the  deed  of  cession  which  they 
had  made  over  to  Dr.  Ayres  and  Captain  Stockton,  caused 
hard  feeling  between  the  colonists  and  the  natives.  Ash- 
mun saw  at  once  that  he  must  look  for  friction,  and  he  lost 
no  time  in  putting  the  settlement  in  a  condition  of  military 
defence  for  the  protection  of  the  settlers  who  were  then 
living  at  Montserado.  Several  attacks  were  made  by  the 
natives,  but  altogether  without  success.  The  defeated  na- 
tives acquiesced  in  the  occupation  of  the  land  they  had 
ceded  to  the  agents.6*  April  25,  1822,  the  American  flag 
was  for  the  first  time  hoisted  on  Cape  Montserado. 

By  1823  the  Managers  of  the  Society  had  become  again 

58  Half-Century  Memorial  of  American  Colonization  Society,  1867, 
p.  83. 

od  Lugenbeel. 
«o  Ibid. 


381]  ORGANIZATION,  PURPOSE,  EARLY   YEARS  69 

very  hopeful  of  the  success  of  colonization  on  the  West 
Coast  of  Africa.  They  reported  about  a  hundred  and 
thirty  settlers  at  that  time  living  at  the  Society's  settlement, 
a  regularly  planned  town,  and  great  improvement  in  the 
health  of  the  colonists,  although  Mrs.  Ashmun  had  died 
since  her  arrival  in  Africa.  They  noted  a  rapidly  growing 
desire  among  the  free  negroes  of  America  to  emigrate  to 
the  settlement,  and 

when  they  reflect  upon  the  frequency  of  manumissions,  wherever  the 
law  has  imposed  no  restrictions,  when  they  consider  the  power  of 
example  .  .  .,  and  especially  when  they  recollect  the  institutions  of 
their  country,  and  the  light  of  the  age,  they  are  induced  to  expect 
that,  should  prosperity  attend  the  colony,  thousands  now  in  servi- 
tude amongst  us  will  one  day  be  freemen  in  the  land  of  their 
ancestors.61 

Dr.  Ayres,  who  had  returned  to  Africa  after  his  visit  to 
the  United  States,  was  instructed  to  negotiate  with  the  na- 
tive kings  for  a  "much  larger  extent  of  country  than  we 
now  possess  on  that  continent."62  An  appeal  went  out  from 
the  Managers  for  more  funds  to  meet  the  opportunities  that 
were  dawning  upon  the  enterprise.  They  appealed  for  the 
means  to  send  emigrants  in  sufficient  numbers  to  render 
their  presence  along  the  coast  a  "  security  from  the  intrigues 
of  slave  traders,"  and  to  protect  the  settlements  from  the 
"cupidity  of  neighboring  tribes."  Also,  "abundant  infor- 
mation has  been  laid  before  the  Board  ...  to  warrant  the 
declaration  that  numerous  slave  holders  would  send,  some 
a  portion,  and  others  the  whole  of  their  slaves  to  the  colony, 
as  soon  as  they  are  convinced  that  the  colony  is  prepared 
for  their  reception,  and  that  their  condition  would  be  im- 
proved by  the  removal."63 

In  view  of  the  often  repeated  charge  made  by  the  ultra- 
abolitionists  that,  between  the  African  fever  and  the  bar- 
barity of  the  native  tribes,  the  Society  was  sacrificing  the 

61  Origin,  Constitution,  and  Proceedings  of  American  Coloniza- 
tion Society,  MS.,  vol.  i,  pp.  198-221,  Sixth  Annual  Report  of  the 
Board  of  Managers,  1823. 

62  Minutes  of  Board  of  Managers  of  American  Colonization  So- 
ciety, MS.,  March  28,  1823. 

68  Ibid.,  June  4,  1823. 


7O  THE  AMERICAN   COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [382 

American  free  negro  for  its  own  selfish  and  unworthy  aims, 
it  will  be  not  without  interest  to  call  attention  to  a  report  of 
the  Managers,  early  in  1824.  Since  the  origin  of  the  So- 
ciety, two  hundred  and  twenty-five  emigrants  had  sailed  for 
the  African  coast.  The  number  in  the  colony  at  the  time 
of  the  report  was  one  hundred  and  forty,  a  number  of  those 
missing  having  gone  to  Sierra  Leone  to  live;  several  had 
returned  to  the  United  States,  and  only  forty  deaths  had 
been  reported.  Of  these  forty,  twenty-two  were  passengers 
on  the  Elizabeth.  Only  four  deaths  had  resulted  from  con- 
flicts with  the  natives ;  two  had  been  drowned,  one  had  died 
of  old  age,  one  died  through  his  own  rashness,  and  four 
were  children  under  four  years  of  age.64  Indeed,  the  Mana- 
gers thought  this  a  very  hopeful  beginning,  and  others  evi- 
dently agreed  with  them,  for  the  Presbyterian  Synods  of 
Philadelphia  and  Virginia  had  approved  the  efforts  of  the 
Society,  as  had  also  the  General  Convention  of  the  Prot- 
estant Episcopal  Church,  the  first  two,  unanimously.  And 
as  for  the  possibility  of  securing  emigrants,  it  was  the  opin- 
ion of  the  Board  that  "the  means  will  never  equal  the  de- 
mand for  transportation."*5 

The  Managers,  who  had  again  memorialized  Congress  in 
1822,  urging  further  restrictive  measures  against  the"  Afri- 
can slave  trade,66  adopted  the  recommendations  of  a  com- 
mittee appointed  to  consider  the  advisability  of  requesting 
further  aid  from  Congress.  The  committee  expressed  the 
opinion  that  "  it  [the  scheme  of  colonization]  is  well  known 
to  be  far  too  great,  to  be  sensibly  affected  by  any  resources 
which  an  association  of  individuals  can  command.  To  the 
nation,  and  to  the  nation  alone,  must  we  look  for  adequate 
means  of  accomplishing  such  a  work."  It  was  recom- 
mended that  Congress  be  asked  to  take  under  its  protection 
the  colony  already  planted,  to  provide  appropriations  for 
its  development,  to  make  further  purchases  of  territory,  to 

64  Origin,  Constitution,  and  Proceedings  of  American  Coloniza- 
tion Society,  MS.,  vol.  i,  pp.  231-232. 

65  Ibid.,  vol.  i,  pp.  244-253. 
68  Ibid.,  vol.  i,  p.  182. 


383]  ORGANIZATION,  PURPOSE,  EARLY   YEARS  ?I 

supply  it  with  a  force  adequate  for  its  military  defence,  and 
to  enact  regulations  for  its  temporary  government.  It  was 
also  recommended  to  petition  Congress  to  incorporate  the 
Society  in  the  District  of  Columbia.67  The  petition  that  re- 
sulted went  the  way  of  all  other  petitions  whose  aim  was  to 
secure  direct  financial  aid  from  Congress. 

At  the  annual  meeting  in  February,  1824,  on  the  motion 
of  General  Robert  G.  Harper,  the  territory  that  had  been  se- 
cured was  named  Liberia,  and  the  settlement  made  was  named 
after  the  President  of  the  United  States,  Monrovia.  Early 
in  this  year  a  remonstrance  from  the  Liberian  settlements 
reached  the  officers  of  the  Society.  Although  great  care 
was  taken  to  send  out  to  the  settlement  only  those  who  were 
believed  to  be  desirable  immigrants,  the  government  of  the 
Liberians  by  direction  of  the  Society  soon  began  to  present 
added  problems.  Dissatisfaction  among  the  few  settlers 
had  reached  such  a  point  that  four  documents  and  a  special 
agent  were  sent  to  Liberia  before  the  colonial  agent  was 
able  to  restore  peace  and  order.  The  settlers  complained, 
first,  that  lots  had  not  been  distributed  to  immigrants  in 
accordance  with  instructions  of  the  Board  of  Managers; 
second,  that  it  was  impracticable  for  settlers  to  obey  the 
regulations  requiring  them  to  erect,  each  on  his  lot,  a  dwell- 
ing, within  two  years  of  his  selection  of  the  lot ;  third,  that, 
because  of  the  return  of  Dr.  Ayres  to  the  United  States,  the 
Managers  evidently  intended  to  abandon  the  settlers  in  a 
strange  land;  fourth,  that  certain  settlers  were  being  dis- 
criminated against,  by  the  government,  in  favor  of  other 
settlers;  and  finally,  that  they  were  dissatisfied  with  the 
agents.  The  reply  of  the  Managers  is  conclusive  and  sets 
forth  beyond  doubt  the  fact  that  the  complaints  were 
founded  upon  ignorance  of  the  facts,  although  it  is  prob- 
ably true  that  no  adequate  instructions  and  no  definite  and 
detailed  scheme  had  ever  been  sent  out  to  the  agent  for  the 
government  of  the  colony.  Direct,  and  probably  useful 
advice  was  given  in  the  following  words : 

87  Ibid.,  vol.  i,  pp.  272-276. 


72  THE  AMERICAN    COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [384 

Let  us  not  be  misunderstood.  ...  It  is  our  intention  now  and  all 
times  to  distinguish  between  the  industrious,  the  provident,  the  or- 
derly and  useful  citizens — and  those  who  are  lazy,  disorderly,  and 
hurtful  to  the  settlement.  We  wish  it  to  be  explicitly  understood, 
that  we  will  not  extend  .  .  .  indulgence  to  the  lazy  and  the  disor- 
derly. ...  It  would  give  us  great  pleasure  if  we  had  the  means  to 
extend  our  supplies  to  those  who  would  properly  value  and  make 
good  use  of  them.  We  have  begged  through  the  country — we  have 
begged  of  Congress  and  of  the  State  Legislatures — we  are  constantly 
begging  and  contributing  ourselves.  You  receive  all  the  benefit  of 
it.  Those  who  are  not  satisfied  with  this,  will  be  satisfied  with 
nothing.68 

During  the  disorders  in  the  colony,  the  Society's  agent 
was  insulted  and  abused,  public  authority  was  defied,  and 
an  armed  force  had  taken  possession  of,  and  robbed,  the 
public  storehouse,  and  the  Managers,  in  an  address  to  the 
Citizens  of  Liberia,  say :  "  This  is  the  very  conduct  repeat- 
edly predicted  by  our  opponents;  we  have  been  told  over 
and  over  again  that  you  would  not  submit  to  any  law  or 
government  without  an  armed  force;  we  have  constantly 
repelled  these  reproaches  on  your  character  as  unjust;  what 
shall  we  now  say?"  The  address  _was  characterized  by 
firmness,  but  also  by  kindness ;  and  it  was  rather  by  an  ap- 
peal to  their  reason  than  by  threats  of  punishment  that  the 
Managers  called  upon  the  colonists  to  submit  to  rightful 
authority  and  settle  their  differences.69  In  their  general 
instructions  to  the  colonial  agent,  Mr.  Ashmun,  the  Mana- 
gers speak  of  the  "wicked  combination  and  disgraceful 
proceedings  of  Lot  Carey  and  others.  .  .  ."  "  Such  pro- 
ceedings, if  repeated,  must  inevitably  lead  to  the  destruc- 
tion of  the  Colony."  The  mildest  punishment  consistent 
with  the  reestablishment  of  order  was  to  be  inflicted;  the 
arms  were  to  be  taken  away  from  those  who  had  had  a  part 
in  the  rioting;  civil  officers,  among  the  offenders,  were  to 
have  their  commissions  revoked.  Carey,  himself  a  minis- 
ter, was  to  abstain  from  the  further  exercise  of  his  minis- 
terial function  "till  time  and  circumstances  shall  have  evi- 
denced the  deepness  and  sincerity  of  his  repentance."70 

68  Minutes  of  Board  of  Managers  of  American  Colonization  So- 
ciety, MS.,  March  20,  1824. 

69  Ibid.,  March  20,  1824. 

70  Ibid.,  vol.  i,  p.  201. 


385]  ORGANIZATION,  PURPOSE,  EARLY   YEARS  73 

In  private  instructions,  the  agent  was  criticised  for  not 
having  promptly  resisted  the  first  expression  of  "  insolent 
and  abusive  language  "  toward  him ;  and  he  was  instructed : 
"...  keep  your  arms  by  you,  or  near  you.  Never  con- 
tinue altercation,  where  there  are  symptoms  of  passion. 
.  .  .  Stop  the  rations  of  every  one  who  refuses  to  labour 
in  the  public  service  according  to  their  oaths  and  engage- 
ments. If  this  will  not  do  they  must  be  banished."  He 
was  instructed  to  be  as  "mild,  calm,  steady,  firm,"  as  was 
consistent  with  the  necessities  of  the  case.71 

In  addition  to  these  efforts  to  bring  peace  to  Monrovia, 
the  Managers  sent  out  a  special  agent  to  examine  and  report 
on  the  prospects  of  the  colony.  The  man  selected  was  Rev. 
Ralph  Randolph  Gurley,  a  graduate  of  Yale  and  a  native 
of  Connecticut  who,  in  1822,  began  a  connection  with  the 
central  office  of  the  American  Colonization  Society,  where 
he  gained  a  reputation  as  editor  and  orator  that  was  not 
only  coextensive  with  the  limits  of  the  Union,  but  that  ex- 
tended to  England  and  Scotland.  From  1822  to  1840  he 
did  more  than  any  other  single  man  connected  with  the  So- 
ciety— and  many  men  thought,  as  much  as  almost  any  half 
dozen  men — to  keep  open  the  avenues  of  thought  and  sym- 
pathy and  cooperation  between  the  biggest  and  best  of  men 
in  every  part  of  the  Union.  Utterly  unlike  in  their  private 
practices,  what  Henry  Clay  was  in  the  Halls  of  Congress, 
Gurley  was  to  Colonization,  essentially  a  peacemaker  and 
a  lover  of  the  Union.  Those  who,  following  Garrison  and 
his  partisans,  charge  the  colonization  movement  with  being 
a  move  to  rivet  the  chains  of  the  slaves,  and  base  their  con- 
tention upon  the  fact  that  every  President  of  the  Society, 
from  its  organization  to  near  the  opening  of  the  Civil  War, 
was  a  holder  of  slaves,  must  be  ignorant  of  the  fact  that 
Gurley's  influence  during  those  years  of  his  active  leader- 
ship was  so  much  greater,  in  molding  the  policies  of  the 
Society,  than  that  of  any  of  these  presidents,  that  it  would 
be  ridiculous  to  compare  it  with  the  influence  of  any,  or  all, 
of  them. 

71  Ibid.,  April  i,  1824. 


74  THE  AMERICAN    COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [386 

Elliot  Cresson,  one  of  the  most  persistent  Colonizationists 
in  the  history  of  the  Society,  used  to  call  the  second  Presi- 
dent, Charles  Carroll  of  Carrollton,  "The  Great  Incubus." 
Those  who  would  understand  the  platform  of  the  Coloniza- 
tion movement  must  consult,  not  the  list  of  slaveholding 
presidents  who  were  the  official  heads  of  the  organization, 
although,  with  the  possible  exception  of  Carroll,  not  a  presi- 
dent of  the  Society  has  ever  been  a  proponent  of  slavery, 
notwithstanding  the  fact  that  the  first  four  of  them  were 
holders  of  negro  slaves  (and  the  two  phrases  are  by  no 
means  synonymous  to  those  who  realize  that  slavery  was  a 
problem),  but  the  secretaries  and  the  boards  of  managers 
and  directors,  for  these  were  the  molders  of  policy.  Dur- 
ing those  years  of  bitter  struggle,  between  1830  and  1840, 
Gurley  stands  out  as  the  great  Colonizationist.  He  was  the 
one  man  who  held  in  the  hollow  of  his  hand  the  confidence 
of  moderate  men  throughout  the  United  States,  on  the  sub- 
ject of  slavery.  He  was  undoubtedly  a  poor  guardian  of 
the  Society's  exchequer.  He  wrought  mightily  with  the 
pen  and  played  havoc  with  the  purse.  But  of  all  the  charges 
that  were  made  against  him  by  extremists  in  England  and 
America,  not  one  has  resulted  in  his  conviction  at  the  bar 
of  public  opinion.  When  he  was  superseded,  a  nation-wide 
protest,  but  a  protest  particularly  from  the  South,  went  up. 
While  Garrison  was  actively  and  consciously  engaged  in 
pulling  the  Union  to  pieces,  Gurley  was  traveling  from 
North  to  South,  from  East  to  West,  observing  the  results 
of  radicalism  and  dreading  the  aftermath.  An  accurate 
biography  of  Gurley  would  throw  a  new  and  not  favorable 
light  upon  the  results  of  Garrisonism. 

This  man  was  about  to  perform  his  first  important  service 
to  the  cause  of  Colonization.  He  met  Ashmun  at  the  Cape 
Verde  Islands,  whither  the  latter  had  been  compelled  to  go, 
for  rest  and  recuperation,  and  the  two  proceeded  to  Liberia. 
After  ten  days,  Gurley  left  for  America,  leaving  Ashmun 
commissions  which,  like  his  own,  were  from  both  the  Gov- 
ernment and  the  Society.72  When  Gurley  presented  to  the 

TZ  Lugenbeel. 


387]  ORGANIZATION,  PURPOSE,  EARLY   YEARS  /$ 

Managers  his  proposed  constitution  for  the  government  of 
the  colony,  it  was  received  with  disappointment.  "The 
Board  think  it  much  too  complicated  and  intricate  for  the 
simplicity  of  a  few  settlers.  .  .  .  We  wish  the  settlement 
founded  in  republican  simplicity  and  Christian  plainness — 
all  unnecessary  offices  and  dignities  and  official  titles  ought 
to  be  avoided."78  But  after  six  months'  experiment,  the 
instrument  had  proved  so  satisfactory  that  the  Board  with- 
drew its  objection  and  officially  approved  it.74  In  his  re- 
port to  the  Managers,  Gurley  expressed  great  satisfaction 
with  the  location  of  the  settlement,  the  fertility  of  the  soil, 
the  health  of  the  colonists,  their  general  intelligence,  their 
Sunday  Schools.  He  was  convinced,  however,  that  the 
government  was  too  feeble,  and  that  several  recent  decisions 
of  the  Board  had  been  received  with  dissatisfaction  among 
the  colonists.  He  noted  the  need  for  •  medicines,  agricul- 
tural implements,  etc.75 

The  years  1825-1830  were  years  of  rapid  progress  and 
expansion  of  the  colonization  scheme  in  the  United  States. 
The  few  settlers  who  began  to  return  exerted  an  influence 
favorable  to  the  spread  of  sentiment  among  the  blacks  in 
favor  of  emigration,76  though  some  who  returned  opposed 
the  colony.  The  opportunities  of  the  Society,  during  this 
whole  period,  far  exceeded  its  ability  to  take  advantage  of 
them.  It  was  unable  to  afford  the  means  of  transportation 
for  those  who  applied  for  passage.  It  did  a  great  service 
in  bringing  about  an  interchange  of  views  between  leading 
men  in  the  South  Middle  States  and  the  New  England 
States  by  sending  such  men  as  Charles  Fenton  Mercer  and 
J.  B.  Harrison  to  meet  with  the  legislature  and  to  converse 
privately  with  leaders  in  New  York  and  the  New  England 

7>  Minutes  of  Board  of  Managers  of  American  Colonization  So- 
ciety, MS.,  Nov.  13,  1824. 

7*Ibid.,  May  18,  1825. 

78  Origin,  Constitution,  and  Proceedings  of  American  Coloniza- 
tion Society,  MS.,  vol.  i,  p.  277  ff . 

78  Minutes  of  Board  of  Managers  of  American  Colonization  So- 
ciety, MS.,  Dec.  22,  1825. 


76  THE   AMERICAN    COLONIZATION    SOCIETY  [388 

States.77  Memorials  were  presented  to  legislatures  of  the 
several  States,  asking  their  approbation  of  the  objects  of 
the  Society  and  their  pecuniary  support.78  The  Society  en- 
listed important  workers  when  it  adopted  the  suggestion  of 
J.  H.  B.  Latrobe,  that  the  ladies  of  the  Union  be  invited  to 
organize  female  societies  "  for  the  purpose  of  aiding  in  the 
collection  of  funds  by  procuring  donations,  holding  fairs, 
etc.,  etc. — that  this  be  put  into  the  form  of  a  resolution, 
prefaced  by  some  general  remarks — '  female  sensibility — 
sympathy ' — etc.  etc.  etc.  and  then  published  as  a  circular." 
It  also  sought  to  make  the  means  that  it  had  count  for  most 
in  the  colony,  by  refusing  to  transport  to  Africa  any  free 
negro  over  fifty  years  of  age,  unless  he  was  a  member  of  a 
family  that  was  emigrating  to  Liberia;  and  by  refusing, 
except  in  extreme  cases,  to  give  more  than  six  months'  sub- 
sistence to  colonists  after  their  arrival  at  the  settlement.79 

At  the  annual  meeting  in  1827,  Henry  Clay  made  an  im- 
portant speech,  voicing  the  disappointment  that  was  felt  by 
the  managers  at  the  continued  refusal  of  Congress  to  appro- 
priate funds  for  the  cause.  He  was  sure  that  the  Society 
had  been  organized  merely  as  a  pioneer  in  the  work,  and 
conscious  of  its  inability  to  carry  out  its  program  without 
the  support  of  Federal  or  State  governments,  or  both.  He 
realized  that  assistance  had  been  denied  it  largely  because 
it  had  been  compelled  to  stand  between  two  violent  cross- 
fires of  public  criticism. 

According  to  one  (that  rash  class  which,  without  a  due  estimate 
of  the  fatal  consequence,  would  forthwith  issue  a  decree  of  general, 
immediate,  and  indiscriminate  emancipation)  it  was  a  scheme  of  the 
slaveholder  to  perpetuate  slavery.  The  other,  (that  class  which  be- 
lieves slavery  a  blessing,  and  which  trembles  with  aspen  sensibility 
at  the  appearance  of  the  most  distant  and  ideal  danger  to  the  tenure 
by  which  that  description  of  property  is  held,)  declared  it  a  con- 
trivance to  let  loose  on  society  all  the  slaves  of  the  country.  .  .  . 

He  believed  that,  hereafter,  the  population  of  the  United 
States  would  duplicate  itself  not  oftener  than  once  in  every 

™  Ibid.,  May  10,  1825 ;  Jan.  24,  1828. 
« Ibid.,  Mar.  4,  1825 ;  Sept.  24,  1827. 
"Ibid.,  Jan.  12,  1829;  Sept.  24,  1829. 


389]  ORGANIZATION,  PURPOSE,  EARLY   YEARS  77 

thirty- three  years.  If,  during  the  next  period  of  duplica- 
tion, he  said,  "  the  capital  of  the  African  stock  could  be  kept 
down,  or  stationary,  whilst  that  of  European  origin  should 
be  left  to  an  unobstructed  increase,  the  result,  at  the  end  of 
the  term,  would  be  most  propitious,"  and  at  the  end  of  two 
terms,  would  leave  the  proportion  of  black  to  white  approxi- 
mately one  to  twenty.  Now,  he  thought  it  practicable  to 
transport  the  annual  increase  of  the  whole  colored  popula- 
tion, slave  and  free,  estimated  by  him  to  be  about  52,000. 
The  total  expense  of  sending  this  increase  to  Africa,  each 
year,  would  be  $1,040,000  and  65,000  tons  of  shipping.  Is 
that,  considering  the  magnitude  of  the  object, 

beyond  the  ability  of  this  country?  ...  If  I  could  only  be  instru- 
mental in  ridding  of  this  foul  blot  [slavery]  that  revered  State  that 
gave  me  birth,  or  that  not  less  beloved  State  which  kindly  adopted 
me  as  her  own,  I  would  not  exchange  the  proud  satisfaction  which 
I  should  enjoy,  for  the  honor  of  all  the  triumphs  ever  decreed  to 
the  most  successful  conqueror. 

Of  the  opponents  of  colonization  he  said: 

If  they  succeed,  they  must  go  back  to  the  era  of  our  liberty  and  in- 
dependence, and  muzzle  the  cannon  which  thunders  its  annual  joyous 
return.  They  must  revive  the  slave  trade  with  all  its  train  of  atroci- 
ties. .  .  .  They  must  arrest  the  career  of  South  American  deliver- 
ance from  thraldom.  They  must  blow  out  the  moral  lights  around 
us,  and  extinguish  that  greatest  torch  of  all  which  America  presents 
to  a  benighted  world,  pointing  the  way  to  their  rights,  their  liberties, 
and  their  happiness.  .  .  .  Then,  and  not  till  then,  .  .  .  can  you  per- 
petuate slavery,  and  repress  all  sympathies  and  all  humane  and 
benevolent  efforts  among  freemen,  in  behalf  of  the  unhappy  portion 
of  our  race  who  are  doomed  to  bondage. 

Of  the  future  of  the  Society  he  says,  "I  boldly  and  confi- 
dently anticipate  success."80 

The  managers  undoubtedly  fek  that,  if  the  North  was 
opposed  to  slavery,  and  if  it  regarded  the  presence  of  the 
free  blacks  as  a  source  of  weakness  and  of  danger  to  the 
Union,  and  if  the  slaveholder  was  expected  to  offer  his 
slaves  their  freedom,  they  ought  to  be  able  to  hope  confi- 
dently for  liberal  contributions  from  the  Middle  and  New 
England  States.  But  despite  a  rapidly  growing  sentiment 
favorable  to  the  Society,  despite  active  cooperation  between 

80  African  Repository,  vol.  ii,  pp.  334-345. 


78  THE   AMERICAN    COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [39<> 

the  Secretary  of  the  Navy  and  the  Board  of  Managers,  and 
despite  the  hopeful  future  that  seemed  to  be  opening  upon 
Liberia,  contributions  from  New  England  were  distinctly 
disappointing.81  Expeditions  had  to  be  delayed  or  omitted 
and  negroes  who  desired  passage  had  to  be  refused,  although 
the  Society  did  not  give  up  hope  of  providing  necessary 
funds,  until  it  had  appealed  for  aid,  not  only  through  the 
ordinary  channels,  but  through  the  churches,  State  Legisla- 
tures, and  Masonic  Orders.82  In  1829  the  Managers  pub- 
licly announced  that  the  need  for  funds  was  "  never  so  ur- 
gent as  at  present.  Large  drafts  have  come  on  us  from  the 
Colony,  and  it  is  all-important  that  our  funds  should  be 
greatly  increased,  and  that  speedily." 

If  it  be  asked,  why  did  not  New  England  and  why  did 
not  Congress  grant  to  the  Society  the  funds  that  it  certainly 
needed,  and  without  which  it  was  unable  to  work  most 
effectively,  and  the  lack  of  which  was  the  most  important 
cause  of  the  small  number  of  emigrants  transported  to 
Liberia  and  a  very  important  cause  of  the  comparatively 
small  number,  not  nearly  so  inconsiderable  as  is  generally 
supposed,  of  slaves  whose  liberation  it  secured,  the  answer 
is  not  obvious.  Perhaps  the  most  satisfactory  method  of 
getting  at  the  root  of  the  matter  will  be  to  survey  the  prog- 
ress of  public  sentiment,  on  the  subject  of  colonization, 
from  1820  to  1830. 

In  1818  the  aims  and  efforts  of  the  Society  were  approved 
by  the  General  Assembly  of  the  Presbyterian  Church ;  also 
by  the  Society  of  Friends  of  Greensboro,  North  Carolina; 
by  the  Synod  of  Virginia;  and  by  the  General  Association 
of  Massachusetts.83  Again  in  1823,  and  again  in  1826,  the 
General  Assembly  of  the  Presbyterian  Church  reiterated  its 

81  Origin,  Constitution,  and  Proceedings  of  Ameiican  Coloniza- 
tion Society,  MS.,  Annual  Report,  1825 ;  Minutes  of  Board  of  Mana- 
gers of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  vol.  i,  pp.  358,  359,  369,. 
383,  462,  466,  468,  483. 

82  Minutes  of  Board  of  Managers  of  American  Colonization  So- 
ciety, MS.,  vol.  i,  pp.  372,  374,  410,  428,  429,  430,  463,  504,  5i6,  56X 
664,  665 ;  African  Repository,  vol.  v,  p.  128. 

83  27th  Cong.,  3d  sess.,  H.  Rept  no.  283,  pp.  421-422,  "  Relating  to 
African  Colonization,  etc.,"  MS. 


39 1  ]  ORGANIZATION,  PURPOSE,  EARLY   YEARS  79 

approval  of  the  work  of  the  Society,  as  did  the  General 
Synod  of  the  Dutch  Reformed  Church,  and  the  Episcopal 
Convention  of  Virginia.8*  Before  1826  and  again,  between 
1826  and  1830,  the  General  Conference  of  the  Methodist 
Church  had  approved  the  scheme;  likewise,  the  Baptist  Gen- 
eral Convention.85  In  1827  it  was  heartily  endorsed  by  the 
Massachusetts  and  the  Connecticut  Conventions  of  Congre- 
gational Clergy,  and  by  the  Ohio  Methodist  District  Confer- 
ence.86 But  the  talented  and  well  known  Samuel  M.  Wor- 
cester, college  professor,  senator,  clergyman,  and  writer, 
called  attention  to  a  significant  fact,  in  his  correpondence 
with  the  Society : 

There  is  another  difficulty,  which  you  will  find  opposing  your 
efforts  in  this  Commonwealth.  It  arises  from  the  state  of  religious 
parties.  The  Orthodox  and  Unitarians  seldom  unite  in  the  promo- 
tion of  a  benevolent  object.  Now  it  happens,  that  almost  all  our 
leading  political  men  are  Unitarians.  It  is  not  to  be  disguised  that 
the  influence  of  these  men  is  wanted  to  give  a  State  Society  Auxil- 
iary to  the  A.  C.  S.  a  certain  kind  of  popularity.  At  the  same  time 
the  orthodox  are  the  people  on  whom  you  are  to  rely  for  efficient 
and  permanent  patronage.  Whether  the  two  parties  can  be  brought 
to  act  in  concert  in  regard  to  Colonization,  is  I  think  a  hard 
question.87 

Prior  to  1826  the  legislatures  of  Virginia,  Maryland,  Ten- 
nessee, Ohio,  New  Jersey,  Connecticut,  Rhode  Island  and 
Indiana  had  officially  approved  the  colonization  project  as 
carried  on  by  the  Society.88  In  1827  Vermont  and  Ken- 
tucky expressed  themselves,  through  their  legislatures,  fa- 
vorable to  the  Society,  as  did  Ohio,  and  Kentucky  again,  in 
1828;  Pennsylvania  and  Indiana,  in  1829;  Massachusetts, 
in  1831 ;  and  New  York  and  Maryland,  in  1832.  The  Dela- 
ware Legislature  likewise  gave  its  approval.89  .The  reso- 

8*  African  Repository,  vol.  i,  p.  125 ;  Minutes  of  Board  of  Mana- 
gers of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  June  2,  1823;  27th 
Cong.,  3d  sess..,  H.  Kept.  no.  283,  pp.  421-422. 

86  African  Repository,  vol.  i,  pp.  343-344;  Letters  of  American 
Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Martin  Ruter  to  Gurley,  Cincinnati, 
Ohio,  June  27,  1828. 

86  African  Repository,  vol.  iii,  pp.  118-120. 

87  Letters    of   American    Colonization    Society,    MS.,   Worcester, 
Amherst  College,  Nov.  16,  1829. 

88  African  Repository,  vol.  i,  pp.  343-344. 

88  27th  Cong.,  3d  sess.,  H.  Rept.  no.  283,  pp.  926-936. 


8O  THE   AMERICAN   COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [392 

lution  of  the  Massachusetts  Legislature  was  in  the  following 
words :  "  That  the  Legislature  of  Massachusetts  view  with 
great  interest  the  efforts  made  by  the  American  Colonization 
Society  in  establishing  an  asylum  on  the  Coast  of  Africa 
for  the  free  people  of  color  of  the  United  States ;  and  that, 
in  the  opinion  of  this  Legislature,  it  is  a  subject  eminently 
deserving  the  attention  and  aid  of  Congress,  so  far  as  shall 
be  consistent  with  the  powers  of  Congress,  the  rights  of  the 
several  States  of  the  Union,  and  the  rights  of  the  individuals 
who  are  the  objects  of  those  efforts."  The  Pennsylvania 
Legislature  declared,  "  Their  removal  [that  of  the  free  peo- 
ple of  color]  from  among  us  would  not  only  be  beneficial 
to  them,  but  highly  auspicious  to  the  best  interests  of  our 
country."  The  Indiana  Legislature  expressed  "  unqualified 
approbation." 

As  to  public  sentiment  in  the  Middle  and  New  England 
States,  David  Hale,  of  the  New  York  Journal  of  Commerce, 
said :  "  So  far  as  I  have  been  able  to  understand  public  sen- 
timent here,  it  is  entirely  (among  evangelical  Christians  at 
least)  in  favor  of  the  Society,  and  its  objects  are  believed 
to  be  attainable.  The  principal  thing  to  be  established,  I 
think,  is  a  firm  conviction  that  the  affairs  of  the  Society  are 
always  judiciously  managed.  It  has  been  thought  that  there 
was  in  some  instances  a  want  of  system  and  order."90  One 
of  the  Society's  agents  in  Vermont  reported:  "There  is  a 
very  general  impression  in  these  States  that  we  are  coming 
up  to  the  work  about  as  fast  as  could  be  expected  and  that 
the  Southern  States  are  not  doing  their  part."91  Theodore 
Frelinghuysen  wrote,  of  New  Jersey:  "Public  feeling  is 
against  us — it  regards  the  scheme  as  visionary — and  nothing 
but  an  experiment  conducted  upon  decided  and  liberal  prin- 
ciples will  correct  the  views  of  the  great  majority  of  our 
citizens."92  Jared  Sparks  said :  "  The  cause  is  one  of  great 
importance,  and  cannot  be  supported  with  too  much  zeal  or 
force."98  The  editor  of  the  Vermont  Chronicle  thought: 

90  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Sept.  7,  1826. 

91  Ibid.,  Myron  Tracy  to  Gurley,  Hartford,  Conn.,  October  3,  1826. 

92  Ibid.,  Frelinghuysen,  Newark,  N.  J.,  Feb.  3,  1827. 

93  Ibid.,  Sparks  to  Gurley,  1827. 


393]  ORGANIZATION,  PURPOSE,  EARLY    YEARS  8 1 

"  There  is  not,  we  believe,  another  benevolent  enterprise  on 
earth,  so  well  calculated  to  secure  the  favorable  opinion  and 
enlist  the  hearty  good  will  of  all  men,  as  is  this,  when  its 
objects  and  bearings  are  fully  understood."94  The  Con- 
necticut society  reported,  in  1829 :  "  Only  one  opinion  is  ex- 
pressed among  our  citizens,  and  that  opinion  is  unqualified 
approbation."95 

From  the  South,  particularly  the  lower  South,  reports 
were  not  so  favorable.  A  South  Carolinian  wrote  in  1827 : 
"  I  am  truly  sorry  I  cannot  procure  more  friends  and  aid  to 
the  Society.  I  am  however  determined  to  persevere,  under 
the  belief  that  opposition  will  give  way  to  information. 
This  however  is  the  great  difficulty.  The  press,  in  the  State, 
is  mostly  against  the  Society.  Things  in  its  favor  are  uni- 
formly excluded  and  things  against  it  are  spread  abroad."96 
Rev.  William  Winans,  a  prominent  Mississippi  Methodist 
preacher  and  an  agent  of  the  Society,  wrote :  "  I  am  per- 
suaded that  the  efforts  of  an  agent  would  be  of  vast  impor- 
tance: but  the  selection  must  be  judicious."97  Clergymen 
from  South  Carolina  and  Georgia  reported  much  hostility 
to  the  Society  in  those  States.98 

Of  sentiment  in  Ohio,  one  of  the  general  agents  of  the 
Society,  whose  territory  included  that  State,  reported  very 
favorably.99  Another  agent,  reporting  from  the  same  State, 
said: 

Among  the  members,  we  number  the  Governor,  Auditor  and  Treas- 
urer of  the  State,  Speaker  of  the  Senate,  a  considerable  number  of 
Senators  and  Representatives,  respectable  and  influential  citizens. 
But  sir,  though  the  attempt  will  doubtless  be  triumphant,  I  frankly 
confess,  that  I  have  met  strong  opposition,  resulting  from  ignorance 
of  the  nature  and  design  of  the  A.  C.  Soc.  The  great,  popular 
objection  is,  that  it  is  a  scheme  of  slaveholders,  to  strengthen  the 
bonds  of  slavery,  by  the  removal  of  the  free  blacks.  You  may  say 
that  I  have  the  means,  at  once  of  refuting  these  ungenerous  slan- 

94  African  Repository,  vol.  iv,  p.  142. 

95  Ibid.,  vol.  v,  p.  121. 

96  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  H.  McMellan, 
of  South  Carolina,  Feb.  23,  1827. 

97  Ibid.,  Winans,  Centreville,  Miss.,  Feb.  27,  1827. 

99  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Canton,  Ohio, 
B.  O.  Peers  to  Gurley,  Nov.  i,  1826. 
6 


82  THE  AMERICAN   COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [394 

ders ;  but,  sir,  this  is  hard  to  accomplish,  however  ample  the  means, 
when  men  will  neither  hear  nor  read  and  are  pertinaceously  wedded 
to  their  errors.  The  cause  however,  gains  ground  very  obviously 
and  will  achieve  a  general  conquest.  It  is  the  cause  of  justice,  of 
humanity,  of  God,  and  shall  prevail.100 

Few  men  in  Virginia  were  more  competent  than  W.  M. 
Atkinson,  of  Petersburg,  to  give  an  accurate  report  of  senti- 
ment in  that  State.  In  1827  he  was  greatly  discouraged, 
for  the  success  of  the  Society  in  its  operations  in  the  South. 
He  said : 

To  see  a  people  to  whom  I  am  thus  closely  bound  by  ties  of  affec- 
tion, differing  from  me,  on  any  question  so  important  and  so  inter- 
esting as  this,  would  of  itself  be  painful.  But  there  is  another  and 
a  more  legitimate  source- of  painful  feeling.  One  of  the  strongest 
recommendations  of  the  Colon.  Soc.  in  my  eyes,  has  always  been 
the  indirect  but  powerful  influence  which  I  thought  it  would  exert 
on  the  very  existence  of  that  fell  destroyer  of  the  prosperity  and  the 
morals,  of  our  land,  slavery.  I  hoped  it  would  do  this  by  keeping 
the  public  mind  fixed  on  the  subject,  and  by  showing  the  practica- 
bility of  removing  the  unhappy  race  ...  to  the  land  of  their  fathers, 
whilst  it  carefully  avoided  touching  those  points,  which  could  not 
even  be  discussed  without  awakening  the  most  unkind  and  bitter 
feelings.  Hence  I  regarded  every  friend  gained  by  the  Society  in 
the  larger  slaveholding  States  as  equal  to  two  friends  in  any  other 
region.  .  .  .  Now  I  have  seen  with  deep  regret  that  the  enemies  of 
the  Society  in  this  part  of  Virginia,  (and  I  fear  it'  is  the  case 
throughout  the  Southeastern  States,)  are  increasing  in  number  and 
violence.  .  .  .  Do  you  desire  to  know  the  cause?  So  far  as  I  can 
judge,  (and  I  have  used  all  the  means  in  my  power  to  learn  the  true 
reason,)  it  is  the  application  made  last  winter  and  it  is  supposed  to 
be  renewed  next  winter,  to  Congress  for  aid.  The  people  of  this 
region,  at  least  an  overwhelming  majority  of  them,  believe  that  Con- 
gress have  no  power  to  grant  that  aid.  I  will  not  stop  to  ask 
whether  their  opinions  are  right  or  wrong.  ...  It  is  sufficient  that 
they  do  hold  these  opinions — and  furthermore,  if  upon  any  topic 
they  would  watch  with  double  jealously  the  movements  of  Congress, 
it  is  upon  such  as  are  in  the  most  distant  manner  connected  with 
our  black  population.  ...  I  feel  constrained  to  express  the  opinion 
that  if  the  Managers  and  the  Society  do  persevere  in  making  their 
application  to  Congress  they  do  it  at  the  cost  of  alienating  almost  all 
their  friends  in  the  Southern  Atlantic  States.  Hence  they  must 
lose  not  only  whatever  pecuniary  aid  they  have  expected  from  this 
quarter,  but  they  must  abandon  forever  the  hope,  of  operating  on 
the  public  mind  in  the  manner  above  hinted,  so  as  ultimately  to  exerC 
a  powerful  influence  on  the  total  voluntary  abolition  of  slavery.101 

Yet  General  John  H.  Cocke,  a  prominent  figure  in  the 
colonization  cause,  wrote  more  hopefully  of  Virginia.  He 

100  Ibid.,  Rev.  M.  Henkle,  Columbus,  Ohio,  Jan.  4,  1827. 

101  Ibid.,  Atkinson  to  Gurley,  Petersburg,  Va.,  July  4,  1827. 


395 J  ORGANIZATION,  PURPOSE,  EARLY   YEARS  83 

thought  the  cause  was  gaining  ground,  although  he  thought 
that  political  agitation  had  done  it  injury  in  certain  parts  of 
the  State.102 

The  fact  is  that  it  was  a  very  difficult  matter  to  keep  the 
colonization  movement  entirely  distinct  from  the  discus- 
sions during  political  campaigns.  This  was  true,  not  be- 
cause Colonization  leaders  sought  to  work  through  the 
channels  of  political  parties,  but  because  Colonization  was 
too  meaty  a  bone,  over  which  political  aspirants  could 
harangue,  to  be  entirely  ignored.  In  January,  1827,  La- 
trobe  wrote : 

Clay  I  see  has  been  helping  himself  to  a  ride  on  our  shoulders — 
but  as  he  has  no  doubt  been  of  service  to  us,  I  will  not  scrutinize 
too  closely  into  his  motives.  .  .  .  Weems  [a  Maryland  Congressman, 
who  insisted  on  favoring  Colonization,  in  spite  of  his  unpopularity 
and  his  inability  to  ride  like  a  Clay]  is  an  ass,  aye,  a  very  ass.103 

Of  the  public  men  of  Virginia  who,  in  -1827,  opposed  the 
Society,  William  B.  Giles  stands  out  prominently.  William 
Maxwell,  prominent  in  Virginia  as  college  president,  legis- 
lator, and  Colonizationist,  wrote: 

I  cannot  tell  you  what  you  are  to  think  of  our  Virginia  Assembly, 
for  I  really  don't  know  what  to  think  of  them  myself.  They  cer- 
tainly seem  to  hang  back  most  shabbily  in  this  great  business  of  our 
Society.  But  the  truth  is,  I  suppose,  they  are  many  of  them  still 
wofully  ignorant  of  the  whole  nature  and  progress  of  our  engage- 
ment, and  I  have  had  some  proof  of  it  that  would  amuse  and  amaze 
and  distress  you  all  together. 

But  he  thinks  that  at  the  next  session  of  the  legislature : 

We  shall  be  able  to  obtain  an  act  that  will  please  you — Governor 
Giles  notwithstanding. 

I  should  have  liked  hugely  to  have  taken  this  political  mounte- 
bank in  hand,  as  you  wish  me  to  do ;  but  have  been  restrained  from 
meddling  with  him  for  two  or  three  weighty  reasons.  In  the  first 
place  his  [policies]  are  such  tissues  of  nonsense  and  paganism  that 
they  can  do  no  harm,  I  think,  except  with  incurables,  aly,  he  is 
such  a  prince  of  hoaxers,  and  has  such  power  of  misleading  the 
simple,  and  all  who  are  willing  enough  to  be  duped  by  him,  that  I 
do  not  think  it  would  be  good  policy  to  irritate  [him  into]  more 
active  hostility  against  our  scheme  if  we  can  help  it.  ...  and  lastly, 
I  am  more  and  more  satisfied  that  it  is  our  duty  to  pursue  this  great 
subject  with  the  tone  and  spirit  of  the  gospel  in  meekness  instruct- 

102  Ibid.,  Cocke  to  Gurley,  Fluvanna  County,  Va.,  July  7,  1827. 

103  Ibid.,  Latrobe  to  Gurley,  Baltimore,  Jan.  27,  1827. 


84  THE  AMERICAN    COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [396 

ing  them  that  oppose  themselves  if  peradventure  God  will  give  them 
grace  to  the  acknowledging  of  the  truth.  So  I  shall  let  him  alone, 
for  the  present  at  least — and  especially  since  he  is  become  (by  a 
fantastic  revolution  of  the  wheel  of  fortune)  our  Governor  elect  1 — 
for  which  I  am  most  heartily  sorry  of  course.104 

William  M.  Blackford,  the  most  important  Colonization- 
ist  living  in  Fredericksburg,  Virginia,  wrote,  in  1828: 

I  cannot  forbear  congratulating  you  on  the  active  hostility  to  our 
scheme  of  the  miserable  wretch  now  at  the  head  of  affairs  in  Vir- 
ginia. The  suicidal  infelicity  of  his  arguments  is  never  dangerous 
to  any  cause  but  the  one  he  supports.  I  know  of  several  who  have 
become  friends  simply  because  Giles  is  an  enemy.  Any  scheme  of 
benevolence  within  the  level  of  his  comprehension  or  approbation, 
would  be  received  with  suspicion — and  e  con-verso  his  denunciation 
received  as  highest  praise  and  commendation. 

I  have  reason  to  believe  that  a  great  change  is  about  to  take  place 
in  Virginia — she  will  I  have  no  doubt  become  decidedly  the  advocate 
of  colonization.  The  coming  year  (in  which  the  question  of  con- 
vention will  be  settled)  is  big  with  her  fate. 

I  cannot  omit  to  state,  as  an  evidence  of  the  progress  of  our  cause, 
that  the  announcement  of  our  intention  to  have  a  public  address  ex- 
cited no  other  feeling  than  that  of  approbation,  whereas,  had  anyone 
attempted  some  8  or  10  years  ago  to  make  a  speech  on  the  subject, 
he  would  in  all  probability  have  been  mobbed.106 

It  was  significant  that  the  legislature  refused  to  consider 
resolutions  hostile  to  the  Society,  submitted  by  the  Giles 
party.106 

During  the  years  1827-1829,  the  Society  was  viewed,  at 
least  in  some  of  the  Northern  and  Western  States,  as  a  part 
of  the  Clay  machine.  Clay  had  supported  it  so  consistently 
that  it  was  brought  into  every  contest  in  which  he  was  a 
leading  character.  And  even  today,  his  support  of  it  will 
be  by  many  considered  a  support  purely  for  party  purposes. 
And  yet  Clay's  support  of  colonization  was  the  logical  out- 
come of  his  whole  political  course,  and  any  other  position 
would  have  been  inconsistent  with  the  public  policy  of 
the  man. 

If  now  it  be  asked  again,  why  did  not  Congress  appro- 
priate funds  to  carry  on  the  work  of  the  Society,  the  answer 
may  be  somewhat  simplified  by  this  discussion  of  the  state 

104  Ibid.,  Wm.  Maxwell  to  American  Colonization  Society,  MS., 
Norfolk,  Va.,  Feb.  24,  1827. 

105  Ibid.,  Blackford  to  Gurley,  Feb.  26,  1828. 

106  Ibid.,  D.  J.  Burr,  Richmond,  Va.,  to  Gurley,  March  10,  1828. 


397]  ORGANIZATION,  PURPOSE,  EARLY   YEARS  85 

of  public  opinion  in  the  different  sections  of  the  Union. 
The  congressmen  from  South  Carolina  and  Georgia  would 
not  support  such  an  appropriation  because  South  Carolina 
and  Georgia  were  wedded  to  the  system  of  slavery,  and 
looked  upon  the  Society  as  a  form  of  New  England  aboli- 
tionism.107 The  hostility  was  made  all  the  more  pronounced 
by  the  fact  that  the  political  acrobats  made  capital  of  the 
opposition  and  used  it  as  a  favorite  issue.  They  associated 
it,  in  their  campaigns,  with  the  tariff  and  internal  improve- 
ments. Charles  Coatesworth  Pinckney  who,  ten  years  be- 
fore, had  been  one  of  the  most  liberal  contributors  in 
Charleston  to  the  Society,  was  now  in  1830  calling  the 
scheme  both  cruel  and  absurd.  The  editor  of  the  official 
journal  of  the  Society  sized  up  the  situation  in  these  two 
Southern  States  as  follows : 

Voluntary  emancipation  begins  to  follow  in  the  train  of  Coloniza- 
tion, and  the  advocates  of  perpetual  slavery  are  indignant  at  wit- 
nessing in  effectual  operation,  a  scheme  which  permits  better  men 
than  themselves  to  exercise  without  restraint  the  purest  and  the 
noblest  feelings  of  our  nature.108 

The  opposition  in  Virginia,  and  doubtless  in  North  Caro- 
lina, was  not  from  the  enemies,  but  from  the  friends  of 
colonization.  Even  William  H.  Fitzhugh  had  declared  that, 
firm  as  he  was  in  his  advocacy  of  the  colonization  scheme, 
and  favorable  as  he  was  to  asking  for  an  appropriation 
for  it  from  Congress,  he  would  actively  oppose  such  an 
appropriation  if  he  thought  it  was  not  in  keeping  with  the 
spirit  of  the  Constitution  to  grant  it.  It  was  undoubtedly 
the  belief  in  Virginia  and,  at  least  to  a  considerable  extent, 
in  North  Carolina,  that  such  an  appropriation  was  not  war- 
ranted by  that  instrument.  The  view  of  Atkinson,  a  leader 
in  the  colonization  movement  in  Virginia,  has  already  been 
set  forth.  Rev.  John  Cooke  of  Hanover  County,  Virginia, 

107  Ibid.,  Rev.  Wm.  Meade,  Feb.  21,  1827;  S.  K.  Talmage  to  Gur- 
ley,  Augusta,  Ga.,  May  29,  1829;  Rev.  B.  M.  Palmer,  Charleston,  S. 
C,  Aug.  4,  1830;  African  Repository,  vol.  i,  pp.  161-164,  180-191; 
vol.  ii,  pp.  22-23 »  vol.  iii,  p.  172  ff . ;  vol.  ix,  pp.  228-229 ;  vol.  vi,  p. 
193  ff. ;  Minutes  of  Board  of  Managers  of  American  Colonization 
Society,  Apr.  25,  1831. 

108  African  Repository,  vol.  vi,  pp.  193-209. 


86  THE   AMERICAN    COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [398 

had  been  requested  to  distribute  memorials  praying  for  aid 
for  the  Society  from  Congress.  His  reply  was :  "  Even 
those  who  have  reflected  on  the  subject  and  are  favorably 
disposed  towards  it,  are  generally  opposed  to  Congress  in- 
terfering. I  am  rather  afraid  that,  with  their  present  lim- 
ited knowledge  of  the  subject,  their  many  mistaken  views 
of  it,  and  the  morbid  state  of  feeling  that  exists  about  here 
respecting  the  assumptions  and  implied  powers  of  the  Gen- 
eral Government,  it  will  be  dangerous  to  offer  the  memorial 
for  signatures."109 

Probably  the  most  powerful,  or  at  least  the  most  influen- 
tial, argument  that  was  made  against  federal  appropriation 
in  aid  of  the  Society,  was  that  contained  in  a  report,  pre- 
sented by  Senator  L.  W.  Tazewell,  of  Virginia,  in  reply  to 
many  memorials  asking  that  the  Society  receive  federal  aid. 
The  burden  of  the  argument  was  the  unconstitutionally  of 
appropriating  federal  revenue  for  the  purposes  proposed; 
the  unconstitutionally  of  holding  as  a  dependency  a  colony 
that,  from  its  very  position,  could  never  become  an  integral 
part  of  the  American  system  and  that,  therefore,  was  not 
contemplated  by  the  fathers  of  the  Constitution ;  the  danger 
involved  in  any  effort,  on  the  part  of  the  Federal  Govern- 
ment "to  intrude  itself  within  the  limits  of  the  States,  for 
the  purpose  of  withdrawing  from  them,  an  important  por- 
tion of  their  population  " ;  and  the  probability  that  such  a 
move  would  soon  result  in  the  Federal  Government  being 
called  upon  by  the  States  to  pay  "  something  like  an  equiva- 
lent for  the  slaves,  in  order  to  obtain  their  manumission."110 

Nor  were  these  constitutional  scruples  confined  to  those 
who  lived  in  Virginia.  Gerrit  Smith  himself  doubted  the 
power  of  the  Federal  Government  to  make  appropriations 
for  this  purpose.111  And  he  said  of  the  Van  Buren  men  in 
the  New  York  Legislature,  that  they  were  as  full  of  consti- 

109  Letters  of   American   Colonization   Society,  MS.,  Rev.  John 
Cooke,  Hanover  County,  Va.,  Feb.  9,  1827. 

110  African  Repository,  vol.  iii:  pp.  161-172. 

111  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  G.  Smith,  Jan. 
5,  1830. 


399]  ORGANIZATION,  PURPOSE,  EARLY   YEARS  8/ 

tutional  scruples  as  the  South  Carolinians  were.112  When, 
in  1835,  Clay  made  another  attempt  in  the  Senate,  Maxwell 
thought  that  if  the  Virginia  Legislature  failed  to  take  action 
favorable  to  the  Society,  it  would  be  because  of  the  effort 
made  in  the  federal  body.113  An  agent  of  the  Society  wrote 
in  1837: 

I  have  just  come  from  Mr.  Ritchie's  office,  where  I  found  him 
engaged  in  writing  an  article,  calculated  to  do  away  in  a  great  degree 
the  good  effect  of  what  he  has  said  before ;  and  all  drawn  forth  by 
the  discussion  in  Congress.  ...  It  is  a  matter  of  universal  regret 
among  our  friends  here  that  Mr.  Clay  moved  the  subject  in  Con- 
gress.114 

Among  those  Virginia  colonizationists  who  did  not  agree 
with  their  colonization  brethren  of  the  strict  construction 
school  were  John  Marshall  and  James  Madison.  On  this 
point  they  were  both  prepared  to  admit  the  power  of  the 
Federal  Government  to  offer  aid,  it  seems.  But  they  thought 
the  most  unobjectionable  scheme,  and  the  one  most  likely 
to  overcome  popular  prejudice,  was  that  proposed  by  Rufus 
King  in  the  United  States  Senate,  February  18,  1825 : 

That,  as  the  portion  of  the  existing  funded  debt  of  the  United 
States,  for  the  payment  of  which  the  public  land  of  the  United 
States  is  pledged,  shall  have  been  paid  off,  then  and  thenceforth,  the 
whole  of  the  public  land  of  the  United  States,  with  the  net  proceeds 
of  all  future  sales  thereof,  shall  constitute  and  form  a  fund,  which 
is  hereby  appropriated,  and  the  faith  of  the  United  States  is  hereby 
pledged,  that  the  said  fund  shall  be  inviolably  applied  to  aid  the 
emancipation  of  such  slaves,  within  any  of  the  United  States,  and 
to  aid  the  removal  of  such  slaves,  and  the  removal  of  such  free  per- 
sons of  color,  in  any  of  the  said  States,  as  by  the  laws  of  the  States 
respectively  may  be  allowed  to  be  emancipated,  or  removed,  to  any 
territory  or  country  without  the  limits  of  the  United  States  of 
America. 

Of  this  plan  Marshall  said: 

It  is  undoubtedly  of  great  importance  to  retain  the  countenance  and 
protection  of  the  general  government.  .  .  .  The  power  of  the  gov- 
ernment to  afford  this  aid  is  not,  I  believe,  contested.  I  regret  that 
its  power  to  grant  pecuniary  aid  is  not  equally  free  from  question. 
On  this  subject  I  have  thought  and  still  think  that  the  proposition 
made  by  Mr.  King  in  the  Senate  is  the  most  unexceptionable  and 
the  most  effective  that  can  be  devised.115 

112  Ibid.,  Smith  to  Gurley,  April  16,  1832. 

118  Ibid.,  Rev.  C.  ,W.  Andrews  to  Gurley,  Richmond,  Feb.  i,  1836. 

114  Ibid.,  Rev.  C.  W.  Andrews,  Richmond,  Feb.  i,  1837. 

116  Ibid.,  Marshall  to  Gurley,  Richmond,  Va.,  December  13,  1831. 


88  THE   AMERICAN    COLONIZATION    SOCIETY  [400 

Mr.  Madison  favored,  likewise,  the  plan  of  Mr.  King.  "I 
am  aware,"  he  said,  "of  the  constitutional  obstacle  which 
has  presented  itself ;  but  if  the  general  will  be  reconciled 
to  an  application  of  the  territorial  fund  to  the  removal  of 
the  colored  population,  a  grant  to  Congress  of  the  necessary 
authority,  would  be  carried  with  little  delay  through  the 
forms  of  the  constitution."11* 

The  active  and  open  opposition  of  the  States  of  the  South- 
east, the  constitutional  objections  that  prevailed  in  other  of 
the  Southern  States,  and  in  some  of  the  Middle  States,  and 
the  various  local  opinions  that  predominated  in  portions  of 
New  England  and  the  Western  States,  such  objections,  for 
instance,  as  the  doubt  of  the  practicability  of  the  scheme; 
the  belief  that  pervaded  many  localities  that  the  Society's 
chief  purpose  was  to  increase  the  value  of  slaves;  and  the 
feeling,  now  becoming  deeply  rooted,  that  the  remedy  for 
slavery  was  immediate  emancipation  rather  than  settlement 
on  the  coast  of  Africa — these  causes  are  sufficient  to  ex- 
plain why  the  Society  was  unable  to  secure  from  Congress 
direct  appropriations  in  aid  of  colonization. 

And  so  the  Society  was  forced  to  depend,  at  the  time  of 
its  greatest  promise,  upon  the  contributions  voluntarily  sent 
in.  The  amount  contributed  from  the  year  1820  to  the  end 
of  1830  was  $112,842.89.  The  amount  of  the  expenditures 
during  the  same  period  was  $106,367.72.  The  number  of 
emigrants  transported  to  Liberia  was  1430.  The  total  cost, 
per  emigrant,  including  in  this  amount  not  only  the  trans- 
portation and  subsistence  expenses,  but  also  salaries  paid  to 
officers  of  the  Society  both  in  the  United  States  and  Liberia, 
the  support  of  public  schools,  buildings,  presents  to  native 
kings,  fortifications,  expenses  of  court  house  and  jail  in  the 
colony,  expenses  of  opening  roads,  and  founding  settle- 
ments, was  $74.38.117  In  spite  of  the  criticism  of  the  Aboli- 
tionists that  the  public  was  being  imposed  upon  by  men  who 
used  too  large  a  part  of  the  contributions  in  the  payment  of 

116  African  Repository,  vol.  xiv,  pp.  305-306. 

117  Minutes  of  Board  of  Managers  of  American  Colonization  So- 
ciety, MS.,  Feb.  20,  1834. 


40i] 


ORGANIZATION,  PURPOSE,  EARLY   YEARS 


89 


office  salaries,  it  is  difficult  to  see  how  so  much  could  have 
been  done  with  the  expenditure  of  so  limited  an  amount. 

The  expeditions  of  emigrants  between  1820  and  the  end 
of  1830  are  as  follows,  with  number  of  emigrants,  by 
States  :118 


Year. 

Vessel. 

a 

U 

fc 

U 
t/5 

a 
O 

13 

s 

d 

Q 

£' 

2 

H 

a 

§ 

A 

Total. 

1820 

Elizabeth 

9 

2 

2 

41 

32 

86 

1821 

Nautilus 

24 

8 

32 

1822 

Strong 

26 

10 

36 

1823 

Oswego 

I? 

24 

19 

60 

1424 

Cyrus 

103 

103 

** 

Fidelity 

4 

I 

5 

1825 

Hunter 

48 

17 

I 

66 

1826 

Vine 

32 

33  • 

** 

Indian  Chief 

18 

118 

12 

148 

1827 

Doris 

8 

74 

10 

92 

** 

" 

22 

65 

IS 

104  6 

** 

Randolph 

26 

26 

1828 

Nautilus 

7 

145 

12 

164 

1829 

Harriet 

132 

i 

17 

ISO 

1830 

Liberia 

45 

i 

IO 

I 

S8e 

** 

Montgomery 

30 

2 

30 

7 

I 

70 

** 

Carolinian 

78 

I 

9 

9 

i 

8 

1  06 

Valador 

39 

41 

81* 

Totals. 

18 

580 

4OO 

26 

39 

196 

4 

57 

32 

IO 

8 

63 

1,420 

a  One  also  from  Massachusetts. 
b  Two  from  Delaware. 
cOne  from  Connecticut. 
d  One  from  Alabama. 

Prior  to  1827  the  emigrants  transported  were  nearly  all 
free  negroes ;  after  that  time,  many  of  them  were  recently 
emancipated  slaves  and,  in  very  many  cases,  slaves  who  had 
been  emancipated  or  manumitted  for  the  express  purpose  of 
removal  and  who  would  not  have  been  given  their  liberty 
had  it  not  been  for  the  Colonization  Society.119 

If  the  Society  had  had  the  financial  support  of  the  federal 

118  African  Repository,  vol.  x,  p.  292.    It  will  be  noted  that  the 
total  number  of  emigrants  here  given  is  1420,  whereas  the  number 
reported  by  the  Board  is  1430.    The  cause  of  the  discrepancy  is  not 
apparent. 

119  Lugenbeel. 


9O  THE  AMERICAN    COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [402 

government,  there  is  no  doubt  that  its  operations  would 
have  been  greatly  enlarged  and  that  the  number  of  slaves 
liberated  would  have  reached  far  into  the  thousands.  At 
this  time,  as  at  every  other  time,  up  to  the  proclamation  of 
emancipation,  the  active  directors  of  the  Society,  the  agents, 
the  colonial  agents  and  governors,  and  the  active  members 
in  every  part  of  the  Union  were  opponents  of  slavery,  and 
looked  forward,  some  of  them,  to  its  comparatively  speedy, 
and  by  far  the  larger  number  of  them,  to  its  ultimate,  aboli- 
tion. Fearing  the  increase  of  the  free  negro  population,  the 
legislatures  had  passed  laws  restricting  very  materially  the 
right  to  emancipate  slaves.  Indeed,  emancipation,  without 
the  removal  from  the  State  of  those  emancipated,  was  made 
a  violation  of  the  law.  And  yet,  the  emancipations  went 
on  in  the  Southern  tier  of  the  Middle  Atlantic  States,  and 
there  is  no  telling  how  far  it  would  have  gone  had  the  So- 
ciety's efforts  not  been  circumscribed  by  the  limitation  of 
its  resources.  Monroe  told  Elliott  Cresson  that  he  believed 
the  Society  could  secure  the  emancipation  of  ten  thousand 
slaves  in  the  single  State  of  Virginia  if  it  would  send  them 
to  Liberia.  Undoubtedly  the  Society  was  favorably  known 
in  every  part  of  the  Union  in  1829,  although  its  friends  were 
comparatively  few  in  Georgia  and  South  Carolina. 

It  was  just  at  this  hour  of  triumph  and  of  promise  that 
there  arose,  in  the  North  and  West,  the  most  virulent,  need- 
less, and  unscrupulous  opposition  the  Society  was  ever 
called  on  to  face.  And  this  was  but  one  of  several  causes 
of  the  difficulties  it  had  to  encounter  between  1831  and  1839. 
The  Abolition  offensive,  the  secession  of  auxiliary  societies, 
financial  difficulties,  distress  in  the  colony,  and  a  reorgani- 
zation of  the  Society — these  are  the  topics  of  real  impor- 
tance that  ought  to  be  discussed,  in  a  study  of  its  operations. 

Opposition  from  the  Garrisonians  was  like  a  bolt  from 
the  blue.  Garrison  himself  began  life  a  friend  of  the  So- 
ciety. Arthur  Tappan,  James  G.  Birney,  who  was  for 
months  one  of  its  active  agents,  Gerrit  Smith,  who  gave 
thousands  of  dollars  to  the  Society  before  the  time  of  his 


403]  ORGANIZATION,  PURPOSE,  EARLY   YEARS  9! 

defection — all  these  were  Colonizationists  before  they  were 
Abolitionists.  ^  Garrison  had  addressed  a  Boston  audience 
in  a  speech  favoring  colonization;  it  was  while  he  was 
working  for  the  Society,  not  after  he  went  over  to  the  Gar- 
risonians,  that  Birney  decided  to  give  up  his  slaves ;  Gerrit 
Smith,  up  to  1835,  thought  that  the  Society  was  not  only 
not  pro-slavery,  but  that  it  stressed  emancipation  too  con- 
sistently to  retain  the  active  cooperation  of  the  South.  And 
when  these  men  ceased  to  be  Colonizationists,  they  did  so, 
not  because  they  had  discovered  some  ulterior  and  hidden, 
or  dishonorable  motive.  The  swan  songs  of  Birney  and 
Smith,  each  requiring  a  considerable  part  of  the  issue  of 
the  Liberator  in  which  it  appeared,  were  very  frank  dis- 
avowals of  the  discovery  of  such  motives.  The  opprobrium 
and  the  charges  were  evolutions,  largely  of  Garrison's  mind. 
The  General  Assembly  of  the  Presbyterian  Church  in  1830, 
with  but  four  dissenting  votes  recommended  the  taking  of 
Fourth  of  July  collections  for  the  objects  of  the  Society.120 
John  A.  Dix  of  New  York  wrote,  in  the  same  year:  "The 
current  of  opinion  is  with  the  Institution;  and  it  will  be 
borne  on  to  the  fulfilment  of  its  object."121  Thomas  Clark- 
son,  of  England,  wrote: 

For  myself  I  am  free  to  confess,  that  of  all  the  things  that  have 
been  going  on  in  our  favor  since  1787,  when  the  abolition  of  the 
slave  trade  was  first  seriously  proposed;  that  which  is  now  going 
on  in  the  United  States  is  the  most  important.  It  surpasses  every- 
thing which  has  yet  occurred.  No  sooner  had  your  Colony  been 
established  on  Cape  Mesurado,  than  there  appeared  to  be  a  dispo- 
sition among  the  owners  of  slaves  in  the  U.  S.  to  give  them  freedom 
voluntarily  without  compensation  and  to  allow  them  to  be  sent  to 
the  land  of  their  ancestors.  To  me  this  is  truly  astonishing.122 

Wilberf orce  wrote :  "  You  have  gladdened  my  heart  by  con- 
vincing me,  that  sanguine  as  had  been  my  hopes  of  the  happy 
effects  to  be  produced  by  your  Institution,  all  my  anticipa- 
tions are  scanty  and  cold  compared  with  the  reality."123 

180  African  Repository,  vol.  vi,  p.  91. 

121  Ibid.,  vol.  vi,  pp.  163-169. 

122  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  London,  Oct. 
6,  1831.    E.  Cresson  to  Gurley. 

128  Ibid.,  Cresson  to  Gurley,  Nov.  29,  1831. 


92  THE  AMERICAN    COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [404 

The  whole  State  of  Virginia  was  deeply  stirred  by  the 
Southampton  Insurrection,  as  was  also  at  least  one  neigh- 
boring State,  Maryland,  and  the  cause  was  greatly  re- 
vived.124 In  the  midst  of  Garrison's  tirades,  George  Ban- 
croft and  Governor  Levi  Lincoln,  of  Massachusetts,  were 
both  friends  of  the  Society.125  An  agent  of  the  Society, 
traveling  by  a  circuitous  route  from  New  York  to  Maine, 
had  conversed  with  editors,  clergymen,  and  others  ac- 
quainted with  public  sentiment.  He  reported  that  he  had 
talked  with  from  ninety  to  one  hundred  editors.  Of  these, 
only  four  expressed  hostility  to  the  Society,  one  of  the  four 
being  the  editor  of  the  Liberator.  More  than  nine-tenths 
of  these  editors  expressed  friendly  feeling  towards  the  So- 
ciety. He  had  talked  with  more  than  three  hundred  clergy- 
men, only  three  of  whom  expressed  hostility  to  it.  He 
quoted  very  favorable  resolutions  passed  by  the  Methodist 
District  Conference  of  Penobscot  District,  of  the  Baptist 
Convention  of  Maine,  and  of  the  Baptist  Convention  of 
Massachusetts.126  R.  H.  Toler,  editor  of  the  Lynchburg 
Virginian,  wrote:  "Among  the  people  of  this  section  of 
country,  there  is  very  little  opposition  felt  or  manifested  to 
the  scheme  of  African  Colonization.  Men,  of  all  creeds  in 
politics  and  of  all  sects  in  religion,  cooperate  in  advancing 
its  interests."127  Of  the  Valley  of  Virginia,  William  C. 
Matthews  wrote:  "As  far  as  I  know,  throughout  all  this 
valley,  there  is  an  almost  universal  feeling  in  favor  of  your 
American  Colonization  Society."128 

And  yet  Gurley,  the  Society's  secretary,  writing  from 
Richmond,  Virginia,  where  he  had  gone  during  the  meeting 
of  the  legislature,  wrote  to  a  member  of  the  Board  of 

12*  Ibid.,  Atkinson  to  Gurley,  Petersburg,  Va.,  Sept.  10,  1831 ;  Ben- 
jamin Brand  to  Gurley,  Richmond,  Va.,  Oct.  5,  1831 ;  Brand  to  Gur- 
ley, Richmond,  Va.,  Oct.  8,  1831 ;  Gen.  John  H.  Cocke,  Sr.,  to  Gur- 
ley, Steamboat  on  Chester  Ricer,  Oct.  7,  1831 ;  D.  J.  Burr,  Rich- 
mond, Va.,  Oct.  17,  1831 ;  Wm.  Maxwell,  Nov.  30,  1831. 

126  African  Repository,  vol.  ix,  p.  24. 

126  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Wm.  L.  Stone, 
N.  Y.,  Apr.  19,  1833. 

'  Ibid.,  Toler  to  Gurley,  Lynchburg,  Va.,  Aug.  22,  1833. 

128  Ibid.,  W.  C.  Matthews,  Martinsburg,  Va.,  Aug.  13,  1833. 


405]      ORGANIZATION,  PURPOSE,  EARLY  YEARS         93 

Managers  of  the  Society :  "  We  can  account  for  the  course 
of  the  Legislature  only  by  supposing  either  that  professions 
of  regard  for  colonization  have  been  insincere — that  aboli- 
tionism has  alienated  the  members  from  colonization— or 
that  they  have  changed  their  principles  and  go  for  perpetual 
slavery — something  may  be  owing  to  each  of  these  supposed 
facts."129  To  him  who  is  tolerably  acquainted  with  Vir- 
ginia history,  the  statement  of  Toler  and  that  of  Gurley  are 
full  of  significance.  An  extract  from  a  letter  of  William 
H.  Fitzhugh  to  the  Society  in  1829  will  throw  much  light 
on  these  statements.  Fitzhugh  was  at  that  time  a  member 
of  the  Virginia  legislature. 

We  have  no  chance  to  do  anything  for  the  Col.  Soc.  this  winter, 
nor  indeed  ever  again,  till  our  representation  [the  representation  of 
Eastern  and  Western  Virginia,  in  the  Legislature]  is  equalized.  The 
present  is  the  ablest  legislature  I  have  ever  seen  assembled  here; 
and  it  is  also  completely  drilled  for  party  purposes.  On  the  subject 
of  the  Col.  Soc.  we  can  carry  with  us  the  representatives  of  a  ma- 
jority of  the  people;  but  the  lower  country,  by  its  excess  of  repre- 
sentation, can  control  all  our  movements.  We  have  just  concluded 
one  of  the  most  protracted  as  well  as  able  debates  I  have  ever  heard, 
on  the  subject  of  South  Carolina  opposition  to  the  tariff  .  .  .  one 
of  the  majority  acknowledged,  in  debate,  his  belief  that  these  were 
the  last  resolutions  in  favor  of  State  rights  that  would  ever  be 
passed.  My  own  opinion  is  that  the  effect  of  the  convention  will  be 
to  revolutionize  the  politics  of  Virginia  entirely — "  a  consummation 
most  devoutly  to  be  wished."130 

From  these  statements  and  from  very  many  others  that 
might  be  added,  it  is  evident  that  the  legislature  of  Virginia 
did  not  represent  the  public  opinion  of  the  entire  State,  but 
only  of  the  Eastern  section  of  the  State.  If,  as  the  Aboli- 
tionists were  just  at  this  time  charging,  the  Colonization 
Society  was  an  invention  of  slaveholders  and,  of  course 
primarily  Virginia  slaveholders,  to  increase  the  value  of 
their  slaves,  eastern  Virginia  sentiment  would  have  been 
more  favorable  than  western  Virginia  sentiment  towards 
the  Colonization  Society.  Western  Virginia  was  certainly 
in  no  mood  to  be  foremost  in  favoring  an  organiza- 
tion gotten  up  by  the  slave  owners  of  the  eastern  counties 

129  Ibid.,  Gurley  to  Joseph  Gales,  Richmond,  Va.,  March  16,  1837. 
180  Ibid.,  Fitzhugh  to  Gurley,  Richmond,  Feb.  22,  1829. 


94  THE   AMERICAN    COLONIZATION    SOCIETY  [406 

for  their  own  pecuniary  profit.  The  opposition  between 
these  two  sections  was  active  and  the  hostility  acute,181  and 
particularly  in  the  attitude  each  took  towards  the  question 
of  slavery.  The  fact  that  it  was  the  legislature  that  held 
back  and  the  western  part  of  the  State  that  urged  support 
of  the  Society,  is  very  important  evidence  that  Garrison's 
accusations  were  baseless. 

In  the  West  Clay,  of  Kentucky,  and  Elisha  Whittlesey, 
were  probably  the  most  influential  of  all  the  Colonization- 
ists.  In  the  Southwest,  there  was  zealous  support  of  the 
Society.  Hundreds  of  slaves  were  given  over  to  it  for 
transportation  to  the  Colony.  The  Presbytery  of  Missis- 
sippi, in  1833,  passed  resolutions  expressing  "  unabated  con- 
fidence in  the  principles  and  plans  of  the  American  Coloni- 
zation Society  .  .  .  and  once  more  recommend  it  cordially 
to  their  congregations."132  But  in  South  Carolina  and 
Georgia,  opposition  was  still  pronounced.133  Y.  S.  Grimke 
wrote  from  Charleston :  "  Let  me  advise  for  your  sakes  and 
for  the  sake  of  the  Union,  that  until  this  crisis  be  past  you 
do  not  send  an  agent  at  all,  not  even  to  explain  your  views 
to  the  colored  people, — so  as  to  encourage  them  to  emigrate." 

It  was  just  at  this  time,  when  sentiment  was  very  favor- 
able to  the  Colonization  scheme,  and  when  the  charges  made 
by  Garrison  and  his  coadjutors  were  utterly  out  of  place 
and  uncalled  for,  that  the  storm  of  that  radical  leader  broke 
upon  the  Society.  An  account  of  that  opposition  will  re- 
ceive more  attention  hereafter.  It  is  enough,  here,  to  say 
that  Secretary  Gurley,  writing  from  New  York  in  1834 
declared:  "The  Abolitionists  are  certainly  gaining  ground, 
and  will  carry  a  large  portion  of  the  North  with  them  unless 
we  can  find  agents  of  zeal  and  talent  to  defend  the  cause  in 
this  part  of  the  country."134  In  1835  ne  thought  there  were 

131  C.  H.  Ambler,  Sectionalism  in  Virginia,  passim. 
182  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Pine  Grove, 
Miss.,  Feb.  23,  1834. 

133  Ibid.,  J.  Corning  to  Gurley,  Charleston,  S.  C,  Feb.  10,  1831 ; 
Grimke  to  Gurley,  Charleston,  S.  C,  May  17,  1831 ;  African  Reposi- 
tory, vol.  xiii,  pp.  201-206. 

134  Letters   of   American   Colonization   Society.   MS.,   Gurley  to 
Gales,  N.  Y.,  Apr.  8,  1834. 


407]  ORGANIZATION,  PURPOSE,  EARLY   YEARS  95 

nearly  a  dozen  weekly  newspapers,  besides  many  other  pe- 
riodicals, "  in  great  part  devoted  to  the  work  of  destroying 
the  influence  of  this  Society."135  And  the  influence  that 
resulted  from  the  Abolition  crusade  was  great  and  imme- 
diate, as  will  appear  from  a  letter  from  the  New  England 
philanthropist,  Thomas  H.  Gallaudet:  "But  in  confidence, 
I  must  tell  you,  that  the  Col.  cause  must  recede  in  its  influ- 
ence in  New  England,  unless  it  is  made  to  operate,  (and 
avowedly  so  by  those  who  advocate  it  here),  as  one  of  the 
means  for  the  abolition  of  slavery."136  At  a  later  time  the 
Society  regained  some  of  the  ground  it  had  lost  in  New 
England;  but  for  approximately  ten  years  it  was  almost 
impotent  in  that  section. 

Another  difficulty  was  the  secession  of  auxiliary  socie- 
ties. During  the  decade  from  1830  to  1840,  the  Maryland, 
Pennsylvania,  New  York,  Mississippi,  and  Louisiana  socie- 
ties adopted  policies  either  partially  or  entirely  independent 
of  the  parent  organization.  The  Maryland  Society  was  the 
first  to  assume  an  independent  course,  and  its  independence 
was  practically  complete.  It  established  a  settlement  of  its 
own  at  Cape  Palmas,  miles  south  of  the  older  settlements; 
the  Pennsylvania  and  New  York  societies  established  a  set- 
tlement at  Bassa  Cove,  between  Monrovia  and  Cape  Palmas ; 
the  Mississippi  and  Louisiana  societies  established  a  settle- 
met  at  Sinou.  Eventually  all  these  societies  were  restored 
to  their  auxiliary  relation;  but  during  the  period  of  their 
independent  action  they  were  a  source  of  weakness  to  the 
parent  Society.  With  all  their  good  wishes  at  the  parting, 
they  invariably  competed  with  the  activities  of  the  older 
organization.  Not  only  so;  but  they  almost  nullified  the 
efforts  of  the  Society  to  raise  funds  in  territory  over  which 
they  claimed  jurisdiction.  They  also  sent  out  their  own 
expeditions  and  controlled  their  own  policies,  which  some- 
times fell  short  of  the  requirements  of  wisdom. 

For  instance,  the  Pennsylvania  society,  mindful  of  the 

135  Ibid.,  Gurley,  Washington,  D.  C.,  Mar.  23,  1835. 

136  Ibid.,  Gallaudet  to  Gurley,  Hartford,  Conn.,  July  5,  1838. 


96  THE  AMERICAN    COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [408 

origin  of  the  Keystone  colony,  established  a  settlement  on 
peace  principles,  forbidding  the  possession  or  use  of  arms 
therein.  The  result  was  that  the  Africans  made  an  attack 
which  proved  so  disastrous  that  the  surviving  settlers  had 
to  be  taken  to  a  protected  settlement.  Furthermore,  so 
long  as  the  parent  Society  was  able  to  hold  together  the 
auxiliaries,  it  was  able  to  unify  the  aims  and  feelings  of 
organizations  widely  separated,  in  distance  and  also  in  the 
environment  of  opinion  in  which  they  lived.  Numerous 
societies  under  a  common  head  would  entertain,  in  general, 
a  common  opinion  and  have  common  aims.  Hardly  had 
the  Maryland  Society  seceded  before  its  policy  began  to 
differ  from  that  of  the  American  Colonization  Society. 
And  after  the  withdrawal,  for  many,  though  not  all,  pur- 
poses, of  the  Pennsylvania  and  New  York  Societies,  they 
immediately  began  to  approximate  more  and  more  closely 
the  moderate  Abolitionists  of  the  North.  Separate  action 
on  the  part  of  these  organizations  was  a  severe  blow  to  the 
parent  society,  and  for  years  a  large  part  of  its  energy  was 
directed  to  the  restoration  of  auxiliary  relations. 

The  movement  for  separate  action,  on  the  part  of  the 
Maryland  Society  began,  it  seems,  early  in  1831.  Various 
causes  have  been  given  for  the  action  that  was  then  taken. 
Elliot  Cresson,  whose  zeal  for  Colonization  was  equaled 
only  by  his  exaggerated  views  of  the  business  inefficiency 
of  the  Board  of  Managers  of  the  parent  Society,  declared 
that  the  reason  back  of  Maryland's  defection  was  her  dis- 
trust of  the  Board's  ability  to  handle  properly  the  funds — 
not  the  dishonesty  but  the  business  incompetency  of  it.137 
And  it  is  certainly  true  that  after  repeated  meetings  in  an 
attempt  to  adjust  satisfactorily  the  differences  that  had 
arisen,  for  the  Board  of  Managers  saw  in  Maryland's  action 
the  setting  of  a  precedent  that  was  likely  to  rise  to  plague 
them,  the  point  upon  which  negotiations  were  finally  broken 
off  was  in  the  discussion  upon  the  disposition  of  funds  re- 

"7  Ibid.,  Cresson,  Philadelphia,  Pa.,  Apr.  12,  1831. 


409]  ORGANIZATION,  PURPOSE,  EARLY  YEARS  9/ 

ceived  into  the  Maryland  treasury.138  The  position  of  the 
Maryland  Society  was  stated  by  J.  H.  B.  Latrobe:  "We 
agree  to  make  regular  returns  of  our  receipts  and  expendi- 
tures to  you  and  to  bear  the  expences  of  our  colonists  in 
Africa;  but  not  a  voice  was  heard  in  favor  of  paying  or 
placing  to  your  credit  one  penny  of  our  funds  gross  or  sur- 
plus."139 By  a  committee  of  the  Maryland  Society  it  was 
urged  that  the  State  could  never  be  rid  of  the  incubus  of 
the  free  negro  population  until  a  State  organization,  pre- 
pared to  take  a  more  aggressive  part  in  the  accomplishment 
of  its  purpose  than  a  mere  auxiliary  to  a  national  organi- 
zation could  take,  was  put  into  operation.  The  situation  of 
the  State  and  her  peculiar  problem  made  necessary,  they 
said,  a  separate  organization.140  What  these  peculiar  con- 
ditions were  was  set  forth  as  follows,  by  Latrobe,  in  a  pri- 
vate letter  to  Gurley  in  1834. 

To  prove  Colonization,  two  things  had  to  be  established.  The 
first,  that  colonies  of  colored  people,  capable  of  self-defence,  self 
support,  and  self  government  could  be  founded  on  the  coast  of 
Africa.  Second,  that  by  means  of  these  colonies,  slave-holding 
States  could  be  made  free  States.  The  first  was  proved  by  you. 
The  second  remains  to  be  proved.  Upon  proof  of  the  second  now 
hangs  the  whole  system.  The  first  step  to  be  taken  to  prove  it,  is 
to  get  a  slave-holding  State  to  determine  to  make  the  experiment. 
This,  which,  three  years  ago,  was  hardly  within  the  range  of  any 
reasonable  probability,  has  been  done ;  and  Maryland  is  now  striving 
to  establish  the  second  branch  of  the  proposition,  and  to  prove  that, 
by  means  of  colonies  on  the  coast  of  Africa,  a  slaveholding  State 
may  be  made  a  free  State. 

Now,  it  appears  to  the  Board  of  Managers,  that  the  success  of 
Maryland  will  have  such  all  powerful  effect  upon  Virginia,  Ken- 
tucky, Tennessee,  and  North  Carolina,  that  the  whole  influence  of 
the  friends  of  colonization,  everywhere,  ought  to  be  devoted  to  her 
aid.  If  colonization,  they  think,  were  to  stand  still,  in  every  other 
State,  until  Maryland  succeeded  in  her  undertaking,  yet  provided 
she  did  succeed,  no  mischief  would  be  done,  but,  on  the  contrary,  all 
the  assistance  that  had  been  given  her  would  be  amply  compensated 
by  the  then  omnipotent  influence  of  her  example.141 

188  Minutes  of  Board  of  Managers  of  American  Colonization  So- 
ciety, MS.,  Apr.  4,  1831. 

189  Letters  to  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Latrobe  to  Gur- 
ley, Baltimore,  Md.,  Mar.  30,  1831. 

140  Minutes  of  Board  of  Managers  of  American  Colonization  So- 
ciety, MS.,  Apr.  4,  1831. 

141  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Baltimore,  Md., 
Latrobe  to  Gurley,  December  29,  1834. 

7 


98  THE  AMERICAN   COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [410 

The  Board  of  Managers  made  a  very  earnest  attempt  to 
dissuade  the  Maryland  Society  from  independent  action. 
They  called  attention  to  the  fact  that  the  views  of  Coloniza- 
tionists  in  different  parts  of  the  country  had  already  begun 
to  vary  widely,  and  "  the  friends  of  the  cause  are  beginning 
to  operate  in  their  several  ways,  a  multiplicity  of  interests 
will  engender  collision  of  views  and  of  vital  interests. 
Hence  it  becomes  and  continues  of  paramount  importance 
that  some  salutary  control  should  be  concentrated  in  the  Par- 
ent Society."142  In  a  continuation  of  the  policy  of  separate 
action  the  parent  society  would  be  rendered  utterly  impo- 
tent, for  not  only  would  each  of  the  Southern  States  pur- 
suing that  policy,  act  upon  its  own  local  views,  but  the 
Northern  States  Societies,  seeing  that  there  was  no  central 
control  and  no  uniformity  of  policy,  would  discontinue  their 
support.  And  yet,  with  the  most  forceful  protest  it  could 
make,  the  parent  society  saw  that  there  was  no  means  of 
compelling  the  Maryland  Society  to  continue  its  auxiliary 
relation,  and  its  attitude  was  that  of  a  willingness  to  sur- 
render every  point  at  issue,  except  the  vital  one  of  depend- 
ence. Even  this  the  Maryland  Society  compelled  it  to  give 
up  also;  and  from  1833  the  active  operations  of  the  two 
societies  were  entirely  separate,  the  Cape  Palmas  settle- 
ment and  territory  comprising  about  one  thousand  square 
miles  in  the  southern  part  of  Liberia.  Here  Maryland  sent 
her  emigrants  and  established  them  under  laws  which  en- 
tirely excluded  ardent  spirits  from  the  settlement.1*3  Within 
the  next  five  years  the  Maryland  Society  sent  out  nine 
expeditions.144 

In  November,  1833,  requests  came  from  the  Philadelphia 
and  New  York  societies  for  permission  to  act  with  a  con- 
siderable degree  of  independence.  They  desired  to  estab- 
lish jointly  in  Liberia  settlers  taken  out  and  governed,  in 
Africa,  almost  entirely  by  themselves.  The  shadow,  but 

142  Minutes  of  Board  of  Managers  of  American  Colonization  So- 
ciety, MS.,  April  4,  1831. 
148  African  Repository,  vol.  xvii,  pp.  184-186. 
144  Ibid.,  vol.  xiv,  p.  33  S. 


41 1]  ORGANIZATION,  PURPOSE,  EARLY  YEARS  99 

not  the  substance,  of  the  auxiliary  relation  was  to  continue 
as  heretofore.  Undoubtedly  the  most  energetic  and  per- 
sistent agitator  for  this  independent  relation  was  the  Phila^ 
delphian,  Elliot  Cresson,  one  of  the  most  zealous  partizans 
and  certainly  the  most  belligerent  Friend  the  Society  ever 
had.  His  reasons  for  desiring  independence,  he  said,  were : 
(i)  the  inefficient  management  of  the  parent  Board  of 
Managers,  and  (2)  the  unsatisfactory  colonial  governor  re- 
cently appointed  and  sent  out.145  Also,  there  is  no  doubt 
that  Cresson  was  anxious  for  the  establishment,  upon 
Quaker  principles,  of  a  settlement  whose  name  should  be 
Penn,  or  Benezet.  Other  reasons  doubtless  were,  the  com- 
parative inactivity  of  the  parent  Society  in  sending  out  emi- 
grants during  1833,  arising  from  a  want  of  funds ;  also  the 
delivery  of  several  speeches  at  the  annual  meeting,  which 
did  not  meet  with  the  entire  approval  of  the  New  York  or 
Philadelphia  delegates.  Also,  there  is  no  doubt  that  the 
charge  of  Cresson  against  the  colonial  governor  or  agent 
was  general  in  the  North  Middle  States.146 

Gurley  wrote  from  Philadelphia,  where  he  went  in  1835, 
in  an  effort  to  reconcile  the  differences  between  the  Phila- 
delphia and  New  York  Societies,  on  the  one  hand,  and  the 
parent  society,  on  the  other,  suggesting  that  the  demand  for 
independent  action  had  arisen  from  ( I )  "  the  general  senti- 
ment of  the  friends  of  colonization  at  the  North  demanding 
that  colonization  societies  should  be  avowedly  and  decidedly 
hostile  to  slavery,"  and  (2)  "a  distrust  in  the  management 
of  the  Board  at  Washington  utterly  destructive  to  its  influ- 
ence as  the  exclusive  director  of  the  funds."1*7  Indeed,  by 
1834,  there  was  excited  in  the  Northern  colonization  socie- 
ties a  strong,  and  almost  uncontrollable,  tendency  toward 
aggressive  action  on  the  subject  of  slavery,148  and  the  dan- 
ger undoubtedly  was,  not  that  the  Society  would  tend  to 

148  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Cresson,  Phila- 
delphia, Nov.  20,  1833. 

146  Ibid.,  Confidential,  Gurley,  Philadelphia,  Apr.  I,  1834. 

147  Ibid.,  Gurley  to  Board  of  Managers,  Philadelphia,  May  I,  1835. 

148  Ibid.,  Gurley  to  Kendall,  New  York,  May  31,  1834. 


IOO  THE  AMERICAN    COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [412 

perpetuate  slavery,  but  that  it  was  rushing  into  such  radical 
action  that  it  would  lose  once  and  forever  the  cooperation 
of  the  slaveholding  border  States.  And  yet,  it  was  just  at 
this  time  that  The  Liberator  was  spreading  throughout  New 
England  the  "  facts  "  about  the  Society,  that  it  was  a  device 
of  the  slaveholders  to  rivet  the  chains  of  their  slaves !  The 
truth  is  that  The  Liberator  lived  on  sectionalism ;  the  Colo- 
nization Society  would  have  been  killed  by  it. 

The  effort  of  Gurley  in  this  crisis  was  to  inject,  by  coop- 
eration, the  anti-slavery  spirit  of  the  North  into  the  South 
and  bring  about,  by  peaceable  means,  the  gradual  abolition 
of  slavery.  This  danger  of  a  division  among  the  societies, 
so  decided  as  to  result,  in  all  likelihood,  in  a  separate  organi- 
zation of  the  northern  group  of  the  Middle  and  the  New 
England  States,  and  the  resultant  alienation  of  the  South 
from  the  whole  movement,  was  foreseen  and  dreaded  by 
the  Board  of  Managers.  "As  the  population  to  be  espe- 
cially benefitted  by  this  Society  mostly  reside  at  the  South, 
.  .  .,  it  is  of  extreme  importance,  that  the  people  of  the 
North  should  remain  united  with  those  of  the  South,  in  the 
plans  and  measures  that  may  be  devised  and  executed  for 
their  good/'149  But  it  was  again  as  it  had  been  in  the  case 
of  the  Maryland  Society.  The  parent  society  could  argue 
and  urge  but  it  could  not  force  the  Philadelphia  and  New 
York  Societies  to  continue  their  former  relations.  As  Gur- 
ley wrote :  "  If  we  cannot  have  things  as  we  would,  we  must 
do  the  best  we  can."  The  result  was  a  compromise,  but  a 
compromise  in  which  the  associated  societies  got  practically 
all  that  they  asked  for.  In  July,  1834,  preparations  were 
being  made  to  send  to  their  colony  at  Bassa  Cove  one  hun- 
dred slaves  liberated  by  Dr.  Hawes,  of  Virginia.  The  par- 
ent board  commented:  "it  now  presents  the  community 
with  the  spectacle  of  more  than  one  hundred  freemen,  who, 
but  for  it,  would  still  have  been  slaves.  And  one  hundred 
more  are  waiting  merely  till  the  parent  board,  or  its  auxil- 

149  Minutes  of  Board  of  Managers  of  American  Colonization  So- 
ciety, MS.,  July  3,  1834. 


413]  ORGANIZATION,  PURPOSE,  EARLY  YEARS  IOI 

iaries,  possess  the  means  to  place  them  as  freemen  in  the 
same  company."150 

As  Cresson  had  been  the  guiding  spirit  in  the  restlessness 
of  the  Northern  societies  in  their  relations  with  the  parent 
body,  so,  it  seems,  Robert  S.  Finley,  a  son  of  the  Rev.  Rob- 
ert Finley,  who  had  a  leading  part  in  the  organization  of  the 
Society,  was  stirring  up  the  Southwest.  Of  the  two  men 
Gurley  wrote :  "  Finley  and  Cresson  both,  are  excentric  and 
erratic,  but  will  not  fail  to  stir  the  elements  in  their  course." 
And  if  he  said  of  Cresson,  "I  have  just  seen  Mr.  Cresson 
and  heard  only  complaints  from  him  for  three  hours,"  he 
could  have  said  the  same  thing  in  reference  'to  the  direct- 
ness, if  not  the  duration,  of  Mr.  Finley's  remarks.  There 
is  some  probability  that  the  desire  of  the  Louisiana  and 
Mississippi  societies  for  independent  action,  resulted  more 
directly  from  the  efforts  of  Mr.  Finley,  -but  also  more  or 
less  remotely  from  the  encouragement  they  received  from 
both  Latrobe  and  Cresson.101  The  relations  between  the 
Mississippi  and  Louisiana  Societies,  after  they  withdrew 
from  the  status  of  purely  auxiliary  societies,  were  still  far 
from  independent,  and  were  of  comparatively  short  duration. 

So  far  was  the  American  Colonization  Society  from  being 
the  creature  of,  and  under  the  dominance  of,  the  Maryland 
and  Virginia  slaveholder,  we  have  seen  that  Maryland  es- 
tablished an  altogether  distinct  settlement;  and  in  1838  the 
Virginia  Society  was  on  the  verge  of  following  the  example 
of  her  sister  State.  At  the  annual  meeting  of  that  year  a 
motion,  made  by  the  Attorney-General  of  the  State,  Sidney 
S.  Baxter,  to  recommend  to  the  Board  of  Managers  the 
establishment  of  an  independent  colony  in  Liberia,  was  car- 
ried, though  the  Board  of  Managers  did  not  act  favorably 
upon  the  recommendation.152 

A  third  difficulty  that  the  Society  had  to  face  during  this 

"o  Ibid.,  July  3,  1834. 

161  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Gurley  to 
Gales,  Natchez,  Miss.,  May  9,  1836;  Gurley  to  Fendall,  May  11, 1836; 
May  16,  1836;  June  3,  1836. 

182  African  Repository,  vol.  xiv,  p.  120. 


IO2  THE  AMERICAN   COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [414 

eventful  decade  was  the  financial  embarrassment  in  which 
it  found  itself.  There  was  hardly  a  time,  before  the  Civil 
War,  when  the  Society's  opportunities  were  not  limited  by 
its  means.  But  it  usually  managed  to  keep  its  head  above 
water  by  refusing  to  allow  its  expenditures  to  exceed  its 
revenue.  In  1834  the  treasury  was  empty  and  thousands 
of  dollars  were  due,  and  there  was  nothing  with  which  to 
pay.  The  receipts  for  the  three  years,  1831,  1832,  and  1833 
were  $105,606.69;  the  expenditures,  $115,349.91,  leaving  a 
deficit  for  those  years  of  nearly  $10,000.00.  The  number  of 
emigrants  transported  during  the  same  period  was  I339-153 
The  receipts,  which  had  never  been  as  much  as  $20,000.00 
prior  to  1830,  were  $26,583.51  that  year;  and  by  1834,  they 
had  mounted  to  $51,662.95.  But  in  1838  they  were  only 
$ii,597.16*  Of  its  receipts  in  1835,  $4°79-95  had  been  se- 
cured as  donations ;  in  1838,  the  donations  amounted  to  only 
$2,438.73.156  The  hard  times  of  1837  doubtless  had  much 
to  do  with  the  decreasing  revenue  of  the  Society  during  the 
last  years  of  the  decade. 

And  this  was  not  all.  The  ruinous  practice  of  purchasing 
provisions  in  Liberia  on  credit,  and  paying  for  them  by 
writing  drafts  on  the  Board  of  Managers ;  the  very  unsatis- 
factory and  loose  condition  in  which  the  accounts  were  kept ; 
the  accumulation  of  accounts,  and  hence  debts  with  the 
Liberian  merchants,  of  which  the  Managers  were  ignorant ; 
and  the  want  of  care  and  economy  in  Liberia  were  among 
the  causes  of  a  debt  which  the  Board  estimated,  in  1834,  to 
be  between  $45,000  and  $50,000,  and  which  was  later  esti- 
mated to  be  some  ten  to  twenty  thousand  dollars  in  excess 
of  that  amount.156 

How  are  we  to  explain  this  debt?    Of  the  several  con- 

168  Minutes  of  Board  of  Managers  of  American  Colonization  So- 
ciety, MS.,  Feb.  20,  1834. 

184  Ibid.,  Feb.  20,  1834;  African  Repository,  vol.  xii,  p.  28;  vol.  xv, 
p.  18. 

158  African  Repository,  vol.  xii,  p.  28 ;  vol.  xv,  p.  18. 

186  Minutes  of  Board  of  Managers  of  American  Colonization  So- 
ciety, MS.,  Feb.  20,  1834;  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society, 
MS.,  Wilkeson  to  John  Ker,  July  25,  1830,  no.  680. 


415]  ORGANIZATION,  PURPOSE,  EARLY  YEARS  1 03 

tributing  causes,  the  most  important,  in  all  probability,  were 
the  hard  times  of  the  decade  and  the  absence  of  men  of 
business  ability  and  experience  on  the  Board  of  Managers. 
There  has  been  found  no  evidence  whatever  that  any  of 
these  men  were  guilty  of  personal  profit.  Even  The  Lib- 
erator, which  exulted  in  the  debt,  could  make  good  no 
charge  of  dishonesty  against  the  managers.  But  it  was  a 
wise  warning  that  Cresson,  himself  a  successful  business 
man,  gave,  as  early  as  1831,  when  he  said:  "Your  Board 
are  so  terribly  afraid  of  DEBT,  that  to  save  incurring  $1000 
now,  they  subject  themselves  to  two  alternatives — starving 
the  emigrants,  or  being  drawn  on  for  $5000  [bye]  and 
bye."157 

Provisions  should  have  been  purchased  in  the  United 
States,  where  they  could  be  purchased  for  a  reasonable  sum, 
and  the  Board  should  have  kept  itself  regularly  informed 
of  the  amount  of  the  drafts  it  would  be  called  upon  to  pay, 
if,  indeed,  it  allowed  the  drawing  of  drafts  without  its  own 
consent.  It  should  have  refused  to  pay  drafts  for  which 
properly  signed  vouchers  did  not  appear.  These  things  it 
failed  to  do  and,  beginning  about  1832,  its  financial  diffi- 
culties began  to  grow  more  and  more  serious.  By  1833  its 
drafts  were  being  protested  and  soon  its  credit  was  de- 
stroyed.158 It  was  too  late  to  correct  the  mischief  already 
done,  but  the  Managers  made  an  effort  to  introduce  a  more 
businesslike  system  for  the  future.  A  salaried  treasurer 
was  appointed,  and  he  was  to  be  at  all  times  strictly  account- 
able to  the  Board.150 

At  the  annual  meeting  of  the  Society  in  1833,  its  Mana- 
gers were  called  upon  to  submit  a  "  full  and  detailed  state- 
ment "  of  the  origin,  rise,  and  present  condition  of  the  debt. 
Its  reply  was  a  very  frank  statement  of  the  facts  above  set 

18T  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Cresson  to 
Gurley,  Philadelphia,  Apr.  12,  1831. 

158  Ibid.,  Gurley  to  Fendall,  New  York,  June  19,  1833;  T.  W. 
Blight  and  Gerard,  Philadelphia,  June  19,  1833. 

189  Minutes  of  Board  of  Managers  of  American  Colonization  So- 
ciety, MS.,  Aug.  12,  1833. 


IO4  THE   AMERICAN    COLONIZATION    SOCIETY  [416 

forth.  The  opportunities  were  so  great  in  1832,  it  was 
stated,  and  the  tendency  of  the  Society  had  been  so  evi- 
dently to  bring  about  the  suppression  of  the  slave  trade,  the 
enlightenment  and  civilizing  of  Africa,  the  removal  of  the 
"positive  impediments  to  the  free  exercise  of  the  right  to 
emancipate  slaves,"  and  to  transport  to  a  land  where  he 
could  be  not  only  physically  but  also  mentally  and  spirit- 
ually free,  the  "  free "  man  of  the  United  States,  that  the 
Managers  had  been  led  to  undertake  too  much,  and  with  too 
little  means  or  opportunity  for  supervision.  To  correct  the 
trouble,  it  was  proposed  (i)  to  enlarge  the  powers  of  the 
colonial  council,  so  that  the  colonists  might  select  their  own 
officers,  make  their  own  laws,  and  bear  the  expense  of  their 
own  government;  (2)  to  offer  stock  on  a  loan  of  $50,000 
and  provide  a  sinking  fund  to  relieve  them  from  their  pres- 
ent embarrassment.160 

Early  in  1834  Dr.  Mechlin,  the  colonial  agent,  resigned.161 
Whether  true  or  false,  there  had  been  reports  that  in  the 
colony  he  had  been  guilty  of  profligacy.162  And  the  Mana- 
gers subsequently  reported  on  his  agency  with  anything  but 
praise.  Many  of  the  items  in  his  report  were  left  unex- 
plained. Since  1830  over  1800  gallons  of  brandy,  whiskey, 
and  rum  had  been  purchased  in  the  colony,  most  of  it,  they 
believed,  by  Mechlin  himself,  and  used  in  the  trade  with  the 
natives.  Against  this  practice  the  Board  entered  a  solemn 
protest.168  Whatever  blame  for  the  very  poor  state  of  the 
Society's  finances  is  placed  upon  the  Board  of  Managers, 
and  it  would  do  violence  to  the  truth  to  try  to  relieve  them 
of  a  considerable  responsibility  for  it,  that  blame  must  be 
shared  also  by  the  colonial  agent,  for  his  administration  was 
exceedingly  unbusinesslike.  The  Springfield  Republican 
probably  named  the  chief  causes  of  the  financial  difficulty: 

180  Ibid.,  Feb.  20,  1834. 

«i  Ibid.,  Mar.  6,  1834. 

162  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Confident!?  1, 
Gurley  to  Gales,  Philadelphia,  April  i,  1834. 

108  Minutes  of  Board  of  Managers  of  American  Colonization  So- 
ciety, MS.,  July  24,  1834. 


417]  ORGANIZATION,  PURPOSE,  EARLY   YEARS  10$ 

(i)  the  Liberian  merchants,  in  charging  exorbitant  profits 
upon  stores  furnished  the  colonists,  and  to  an  amount  far 
beyond  the  expectation  of  the  Managers,  (2)  the  large  emi- 
gration of  colonists  in  1832,  when  the  Society  was  already 
beginning  to  be  in  debt,  (3)  the  want  of  practical,  business- 
like management  and  supervision  on  the  part  of  the  Man- 
agers.16* 

As  a  part  of  the  Board's  policy  of  retrenchment  to  rid  it 
of  the  debt  was  the  reduction  in  number  of  expeditions  of 
emigrants  to  the  colony.  But  this  step  was  opposed  by  the 
Society's  Northern  friends,  who  thought  that  under  no  cir- 
cumstances should  economy  follow  that  channel.  The  re- 
sult was  that  some  refused  to  give,  so  long  as  emigrants 
were  refused  transportation,  and  that  which  the  Board  had 
supposed  would  result  in  a  saving  really  resulted  in  cutting 
off  a  portion  of  its  revenue.  In  the  annual  meeting  of  1835, 
the  New  York  delegation  made  it  very  plain  that  they  were 
dissatisfied  with  the  business  administration  of  the  Mana- 
gers.165 And  yet  the  funds  of  the  parent  Board  were  being 
still  further  reduced  by  the  fact  that  the  New  York  and 
Pennsylvania  Societies,  in  their  comparative  independence, 
were  collecting  funds  in  the  Kentucky  and  Tennessee  coun- 
try. It  was  this  that  called  forth  the  following  remon- 
strance from  the  Board: 

If,  in  the  opinion  of  auxiliary  societies  .  .  .  the  Parent  Board, 
after  a  toilsome,  gratuitous,  and  measurably  successful  service  of 
eighteen  years  resulting  in  the  establishment  of  a  Christian  Republic 
on  a  heathen  shore,  can  now  be  dispensed  with  advantageously  to 
the  cause  for  which  it  has  made  such  heavy  personal  sacrifices,  and 
encountered  so  many  obstacles,  it  would  willingly  retire  from  its 
trust  .  .  .;  but  ...  if  the  continuance  of  the  Parent  Society  be 
desirable,  its  efficiency  ought  to  be  unimpaired;  and  ...  in  the 
deliberate  judgment  of  this  Board,  the  separate,  independent  action 
of  auxiliary  societies  must  inevitably  lessen  the  resources  of  the 
Parent  Institution,  and  its  importance  in  the  public  eye;  .  .  .  and 
finally  make  the  system  itself  a  victim  to  multiplied  objects  and  dis- 
connected operations.166 

From  this  date  until  the  reorganization  of  the  Society  in 

184  Springfield  Republican,  May  17,  1834. 
66  African  Repository,  vol.  xi,  pp.  44-45. 

166  Minutes  of  Board  of  Managers  of  American  Colonization  So- 
ciety, MS.,  May  12,  1836. 


IO6  THE  AMERICAN   COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [418 

1839,  the  relations  between  the  parent  Society  and  the 
associated  Pennsylvania  and  New  York  Societies  were  pe- 
culiarly exasperating  to  the  parent  Board.  Extraordinary 
bills  were  presented  to  it  by  those  societies,  on  the  one  hand ; 
and  on  the  other,  those  societies  which  had,  at  the  time  of 
the  agreement  on  the  independent  relations  that  the  two 
societies  should  enjoy,  pledged  to  pay  over  to  the  parent 
treasury  annually  a  per  cent  of  their  receipts,  failed  to  meet 
their  obligations  to  the  parent  Board.167  The  result  of  the 
disagreement  was  a  request  by  the  Pennsylvania  Society 
for  the  reorganization  of  the  Society.168  The  meeting  that 
resulted  made  proposals  which  were  very  similar  to  the 
changes  actually  made  at  the  annual  meeting,  in  1839. 

The  unusually  small  revenue  of  the  Society  in  1838  is  to 
be  accounted  for  not  only  by  the  circumstances  to  which  ref- 
erence has  been  made,  but  also  to  the  great  scarcity  of 
money  after  the  panic  of  1837.  The  first  speech  Clay  made, 
as  President  of  the  Society,  January,  1836 — the  preceding 
presidents  of  the  Society  having  been,  with  the  dates  of  their 
election :  Judge  Bushrod  Washington,  Jan.  ist,  1817 ;  Charles 
Carroll  of  Carrollton,  Jan.  i8th,  1830;  James  Madison,  Jan. 
2Oth,  1833 — set  forth  clearly  the  fact  that  the  Society  had 
not  yet  given  up  hope  of  aid  from  the  Federal  Government, 
and  that  a  further  application  might  be  expected  in  the  time 
of  the  Society's  need.169 

But  the  most  interesting  effort  to  bolster  up  the  financial 
affairs  of  the  Society  was  an  appeal  to  the  people  of  the 
United  States,  signed  by  sixty-six  leading  men  of  the  coun- 
try, and  resulting  from  a  meeting  held  in  May,  1838. 
Among  the  signers  were  C.  F.  Mercer ;  Governor  Levi  Lin- 
coln of  Massachusetts ;  John  H.  Prentiss,  the  editor ;  Samuel 
Wilkeson,  New  York  pioneer  and  one  of  the  founders  of 
Buffalo;  Charles  C.  Strattan,  later  governor  of  New  Jer- 
sey; Ex-Governor  Samuel  L.  Southard,  who  was  at  one 

19TIbid.,  Apr.  6,  1837;  Sept.  28,  1837;  Dec.  27,  1837;  June  15,  1838; 
Oct.  16,  1838. 

88  Ibid.,  1838,  passim. 
169  African  Repository,  vol.  xiv,  pp.  17-18 ;  vol.  xix,  p.  369. 


419]  ORGANIZATION,  PURPOSE,  EARLY   YEARS 

time  Secretary  of  the  Navy,  and  served  in  many  important 
offices,  State  and  Federal ;  James  Murry  Mason,  author  of 
the  Fugitive  Slave  Law  of  1850 ;  William  C.  Rives,  United 
States  Senator  and  Minister  to  France;  William  Maxwell, 
college  president,  editor,  lawyer,  and  member, of  the  legisla- 
ture ;  Henry  Clay,  John  Pope,  of  Kentucky,  a  president  pro 
tempore  of  the  United  States  Senate;  Governor  and  Con- 
gressman John  Chambers,  of  Kentucky ;  John  J.  Crittenden, 
twice  attorney-general  and  a  United  States  Senator;  Elisha 
Whittlesey  of  Ohio,  and  Albert  S.  White,  United  States 
Senator  and  railroad  president.  Of  the  sixty-six  signers, 
thirty-five  were  from  the  States  north  of  Virginia,  includ- 
ing two  from  the  District  of  Columbia,  and  excluding  Mary- 
land; twenty-three  were  from  the  States,  Kentucky,  Ten- 
nessee, Ohio,  and  Indiana;  and  eight  were  from  Virginia, 
North  Carolina,  and  Louisiana.170 

A  fourth  difficulty  that  the  Society  had  to  face  was  the 
condition  of  affairs  in  Liberia.  Incompetence  in  the  colony 
was  not  unconnected  with  incompetence  in  the  Board.  If 
the  Board  had  provided  sufficient  supplies  and  sent  them 
with  the  emigrants,  much  of  the  debt  and  much  of  the  dis- 
satisfaction in  Liberia  would  never  have  existed.  In  June, 
1830,  Mechlin,  colonial  agent,  was  in  the  United  States  and 
reported  on  conditions  in  the  colony.  At  that  time,  he 
urged  the  Board  to  make  its  own  purchases  of  provisions 
and  send  them  out  with  the  colonists.  He  warned  them 
that  goods  purchased  of  colonial  merchants  and  paid  for 
by  drafts  on  the  Society  would  be  at  an  advance  of  from 
one  hundred  to  two  hundred  per  cent  over  the  cost  of  the 
same  goods  in  this  country.  Agricultural  implements  were 
needed ;  also  building  tools  and  nails.171  Three  years  later 
he  wrote  from  Liberia  repeating  his  request.  Each  vessel 
of  immigrants  should  bring  also  provisions  for  their  sub- 
sistence for  six  months. 

170  Ibid.,  vol.  xiv,  pp.  130-135. 

171  Letters  of  American   Colonization   Society,  MS.,   Mechlin   to 
Gurley,  Washington,  June,  1830. 


IO8  THE  AMERICAN    COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [420 

The  means  at  the  disposal  of  the  Board  will  thus  be  economized, 
and  the  necessity  of  such  heavy  drafts  from  this  quarter  be  obviated, 
and  a  fruitful  source  of  murmuring  and  dissatisfaction  be  removed. 
.  .  .  The  emigrants  pr.  Brig  Roanoke  were  landed  without  one  ounce 
of  provisions  or  other  supplies,  in  consequence  of  which  I  have  been 
obliged  to  purchase  of  Capt.  Hatch. 

The  arrival  of  the  large  number  of  emigrants  sent  out  in 
1832,  seven  hundred  and  ninety,  two  hundred  and  forty- 
seven  of  whom  were  manumitted  slaves,172  caused  the  agent 
much  embarrassment  on  account  of  inadequate  provision 
for  receiving  them.178  Some  of  the  expeditions  contained 
intelligent  and  industrious  negroes,  but  these  were,  as  a 
class,  free  negroes.  Mechlin  remarked: 

Had  we  for  twelve  or  eighteen  months  past  received  300  or  400 
people  of  this  description  instead  of  the  shoals  of  emancipated  slave* 
who  have  been  landed  on  our  shores,  the  colony  would  have  pre- 
sented a  very  different  aspect,  and  instead  of  the  miserably  depressed 
state  of  agriculture  we  should  have  had  flourishing  plantations.  .  .  .1T4 

Here  was  a  practical  demonstration  of  the  danger  of  a  uni- 
versal and  immediate  emancipation  of  all  the  slaves  in  the 
United  States.  Between  the  crossfire  of  the  Northern  Colo- 
nizationists,  who  demanded  that  more  emigrants  be  sent  out 
and  that  those  who  were  sent  out  should  be  chiefly  those 
emancipated  for  this  express  purpose,  and  the  colonial  gov- 
ernor, who  insisted  that  more  provisions  should  be  pur- 
chased and  sent  with  emigrants  and  that  those  who  were 
sent  out  should  be  not  too  largely  of  the  recent  slave  class, 
there  is  no  doubt  that  the  problems  of  the  Board  were  serious 
and  pressing,  especially  as  the  Southern  slaveholders  were 
supplying  all  the  slaves  the  Society  could  attempt  to  trans- 
port. The  perplexities  of  the  situation  will  be  understood 
when  attention  is  called  to  the  fact  that,  despite  the  advice 
of  the  colonial  agent  to  the  Board,  Elliot  Cresson,  who,  if 
he  was  ignored,  would  have  stirred  up  a  hornet's  nest  from 
Maine  to  Louisiana  in  order  to  gain  his  point,  wrote  to  the 
Society:  "I  would  beg  that  if  only  227  are  slaves,  out  of 
the  800  sent  last  year,  you  will  from  motives  of  sound  pol- 

172  African  Repository,  vol.  viii,  p.  366. 

178  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Mechlin  to 
Gurley,  Liberia,  Feb.  28,  1833. 
"*Ibid. 


42 1 ]  ORGANIZATION,  PURPOSE,  EARLY  YEARS  1 09 

icy,  keep  it  out  of  notice  " ;  and  again,  "  Can  you  from  all 
sources  send  2800  this  year  instead  of  800,  if  funds  are 
found?"175 

Word  began  to  come  from  Liberia  in  1833  that  the  con- 
dition of  the  colonists  was  anything  but  desirable.  Protests 
came  to  the  Managers  from  Maryland  Colonizationists,176 
and  from  other  interested  persons.  J.  B.  Pinney,  one  of 
the  most  successful  agents  the  Society  ever  had,  was  in  Li- 
beria in  1833  and  wrote :  "  At  present  it  is  disheartening  to 
go  among  the  sick.  The  constant  complaint  is  'we  have 
no  sugar,  nor  molasses,  nor  rice/  etc.  etc.  '  We  can  get  no 
fresh  soup,  nor  chicken.' "  Pinney  urged  the .  Board  to 
send  nine  months'  provisions  with  each  vessel  of  emigrants. 
Many  of  the  houses,  too,  were  leaky,  he  said,  and  many 
houses  were  not  ready  for  occupancy,  though  they  were 
badly  needed.  A  great  deal  of  the  distress,  he  thought,  was 
due  to  the  selection  of  an  incompetent  agent,  and  one  who 
lacked  religion,  interest  and  energy.177  Very  unsatisfactory 
accounts  came  also  from  a  number  of  the  colonists.178  Gur- 
ley  himself  admitted  the  distress  in  the  colony,  and  thought 
it  was  due  in  considerable  measure  to  the  incompetency  of 
the  agent.179  In  a  word,  this  was  the  darkest  hour  in  the 
history  of  the  colony.  Its  darkness  was  rendered  all  the 
more  prominent  by  the  fact  that  it  followed  a  period  of 
great  promise  in  Liberia.  Reports  had  been  coming  in  of 
the  prosperity  of  the  colonists,  and  it  was  believed  the  time 
had  come  when  the  operations  of  the  Society  could  with 
safety  be  greatly  enlarged.180 

r5  Ibid.,  Cresson  to  Gurley,  Glasgow,  Scotland,  Mar.  15,  1833. 

176  Ibid.,  C.  C.  Harper  to  Gurley,  Baltimore,  Apr.  13,  1833 ;  Wm. 
L.  Stone  to  Gurley,  New  York,  Mar.   19,  1833;  C.  C.  Harper  to 
Gurley,  Baltimore,  Apr.  24,  1833 ;  Miss  Christian  Blackburn  to  Gur- 
ley, Clay  Mont,  Va.,  May  22,  1833. 

177  Ibid.,  J.  B.  Pinney  to  Gurley,  Liberia,  May  17,  1833. 

178  Ibid.,  Phillip  Moore  to  Gurley,  Liberia,  May  10,  1833 ;  July  27, 
1833 ;  Remus  Harvey  to  Gurley,  Liberia,  July  30,  1833 ;  H.  Teage  to 
Gurley,  Liberia,  July  30,  1833. 

179  Ibid.,  Gurley  to  Kendall,  New  York,  Oct.  4,  1833;  Gurley  to 
Gales,  New  York,  April  17,  1834. 

180  Minutes  of  Board  of  Managers  of  American  Colonization  So- 


IIO  THE  AMERICAN   COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [422 

It  would  be  unjust  to  accuse  the  Board  of  Managers  of  a 
wilful  neglect  of  the  Colony.  The  minutes  of  that  Board 
bear  convincing  testimony  to  the  sincerity  and  philanthropy 
of  those  who  controlled  the  Society.  There  is  no  doubt 
that  the  distress  of  the  colonists  weighed  heavily  upon  those 
Managers.  If,  then,  it  be  asked  what  was  the  cause  of  it 
all,  the  answer  must  be  that  there  were  a  number  of  con- 
tributing causes.  The  following  are  suggested  as  the  most 
important:  (i)  the  lack  of  experienced,  practical,  business 
men  in  the  membership  of  the  Board,  (2)  the  incompetency, 
if  not  the  sheer  negligence,  of  the  colonial  agent,  (3)  the 
insistence  of  Northern  Colonizationists  upon  a  too  vigor- 
ous colonizing  policy,  when  viewed  in  connection  with  the 
preparations  in  Liberia  for  receiving  immigrants,  (4)  the 
importation  of  too  large  a  proportion  of  slaves  among  the 
colonists  and  (5)  the  financial  embarrassments  of  the  So- 
ciety. Finally,  among  the  problems  of  which  it  seems  im- 
portant to  speak  at  this  stage  of  our  inquiry,  is  the  move- 
ment toward  and  the  accomplishment  of  the  reorganization 
of  the  Society. 

The  American  Colonization  Society  was  reorganized  un- 
doubtedly through  the  initiative  of  the  Philadelphia  and 
New  York  Societies.  Among  those  who  urged  such  a 
change,  Elliot  Cresson  was  the  leader.  Of  Cresson,  Isaac 
Orr,  an  agent  of  the  parent  Society,  wrote  in  1830  he  "  has 
the  patronage  of  Philadelphia  under  his  thumb,  to  a  greater 
extent  that  I  dare  tell  him.  .  .  .  And  woe  to  the  day  when 
that  commanding  influence  shall  in  any  way  be  broken  or 
thrown  aside."181  From  1830  until  the  reorganization  had 
been  consummated,  this  belligerent  Friend  lost  no  oppor- 
tunity to  tell  the  Board,  in  the  most  direct  terms,  what  he 
thought  of  them.  He  wrote  Gurley  in  August,  1830: 
"  must  I  believe  that  there  is  something  in  the  atmosphere 
of  your  City  militating  against  the  performance  of  business 

ciety.MS.,  Nov.  22, 1830;  Feb.  28, 1831;  Letters  of  American  Coloni- 
zation Society,  MS.,  Wm.  A.  Weaver  to  Gurley,  Washington,  Dec. 
28,  1831. 
181  Ibid.,  Orr  to  Gurley,  Philadelphia,  July  15,  1830. 


423]      ORGANIZATION,  PURPOSE,  EARLY  YEARS       III 

according  to  universal  usage  elsewhere?"  The  uncertainty 
of  the  Board's  plans  for  sending  out  a  proposed  expedition 
of  emancipated  slaves,  which,  at  the  Board's  request,  he 
had  put  himself  to  considerable  inconvenience  to  arrange 
for,  called  forth  from  him  the  following  remark:  "Your 
Board  give  me  leave  to  write  to  McPhail.  What  am  I  to 
write  about  ?  I  can  form  no  guess  of  their  intentions.  .  .  . 
You  must  select  your  own  vessel  and  relieve  me  from 
further  anxiety  and  chagrin.  Another  such  would  bring 
on  a  nervous  fever  judging  from  what  I  have  already  suf- 
fered." In  the  form  of  a  confidential  postscript,  he  adds: 
"By  the  way  what  a  perverse  set  you  are  at  Washington. 
.  .  ."18a  Again  he  wrote :  "  So  little  does  your  honorable 
and  reverend  Board  seem  to  think  it  worth  while  to  concil- 
iate the  confidence  and  kindly  feelings  of  your  patrons  .  .  . 
that  I  almost  despair  of  ever  getting  a  satisfactory  answer 
to  any  subject  that  I  may  trouble  you  with."183  Again,  he 
writes : 

I  now  demand  your  ultimatum,  promptly;  or  I  forever  wash  my 
hands  of  the  concern.  You  pledged  yourselves  to  send  100  on  the 
nth  October.  Do  you,  I  ask,  intend  to  redeem  that  pledge?  If  so, 
there  is  no  time  to  be  lost.  If  not,  I  will  take  the  advice  of  my 
physician,  go  in  the  country  and  leave  you  to  get  a  vessel  when  it 
suits  you.  .  .  .  Don't  forget  the  sawmill.  It  is  of  first  importance. 
The  plantation  ground  ditto.  Schools  ditto.18* 

In  1833  Cresson  was  in  England  and  Scotland  for  the 
purpose  of  arousing  an  interest  in  favor  of  Colonization 
and  of  undoing  the  influence  of  the  Garrisonians,  who  were 
there  painting  in  the  very  darkest  colors  the  motives  of 
American  Colonizationists.  Of  this  Abolition  influence  in 
the  British  Isles  he  writes :  " .  .  .  unless  you  mean  to  aban- 
don England  ingloriously  to  these  modern  Vandals  you 
must  turn  over  a  new  leaf.  ...  It  is  only  by  laborious 
search,  that  I  occasionally  light  upon  a  straw  to  keep  me 
from  sinking/'185  Upon  his  return,  he  refers  to  Gurley  as 
"that  paragon,"  for  having  as  Cresson  says,  "denounced 

182  Ibid.,  Cresson  to  Gurley,  Aug.  5,  1830. 

1  Ibid.,  Cresson  to  Gurley,  Sept.  6,  1830. 

1  Ibid.,  Cresson  to  Gurley,  Sept.  10,  1830. 
185  Ibid.,  Cresson  to  Gurley,  Glasgow,  Mar.  15,  1833. 


112  THE  AMERICAN   COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [424 

me  for  making  complaint,  after  I  had  in  vain  implored  him 
to  do  the  cause  and  myself  justice  before  the  British  public 
year  after  year."186  But  Gurley  was  so  accustomed  to 
Cresson's  hyperboles  that,  as  he  commented:  "I  have  be- 
come somewhat  hardened  against  them." 

As  Cresson  was  busy  in  the  North  Middle  States  work- 
ing up  sentiment  in  opposition  to  the  existing  organization, 
so  Robert  S.  Finley  was,  in  the  Western  country,  exerting 
a  similar,  though  markedly  less  powerful  influence.  Sum- 
ming up  the  objections  met  with  against  the  methods  of  the 
Board,  he  names  them  as  follows:  (i)  a  want  of  system 
and  energy  in  the  Board  in  the  execution  of  its  plans,  (2) 
failure  to  send  out  expeditions  at  the  time  at  which  they 
were  advertised  to  sail,  (3)  failure  to  establish,  in  Liberia, 
a  settlement  on  the  higher  and  more  healthful  territory,  (4) 
failure,  on  the  part  of  the  officers  of  the  Society,  to  reply 
to  important  communications  from  contributors,  slavehold- 
ers offering  slaves,  persons  asking  for  advice  and  informa- 
tion, and  so  on.18T 

The  testimony  of  these  two  men  contains  an  important 
element  of  truth,  but  both  undoubtedly  went  much  too  far 
in  their  charges  against  the  Managers.  So  far  as  they 
charged  business  incompetency,  they  did  an  important 
service  in  pointing  out  the  need  of  reform ;  so  far  as  they 
charged  dishonesty  and  impure  motives,  their  charges  fall 
completely  to  the  ground.  Not  many  men  realized  the 
heavy  burden  that  rested  upon  the  secretary  of  the  Society. 
A  man,  who,  like  Gurley,  was  admirably  and  primarily  fitted 
to  keep  the  sections  together  and  inspire  in  men  of  every 
part  of  the  Union  an  interest  in  the  cause,  was  not  likely  to 
be  possessed  of  those  qualities  which  make  an  admirable 
office  secretary,  such  a  man,  for  instance,  as  Judge  Samuel 
Wilkeson,  who  was  soon  to  give  new  life  to  the  affairs  of 
the  organization.  Gurley  was  contemplative  rather  than 

186  Ibid.,  Cresson  to  Gales,  Philadelphia,  May  4,  1835. 

187  Ibid.,  Finley  to  Gurley,  Ohio  River,  Sept.  u,  1831 ;  W.  Meade 
to  Gurley,  December  6,  1831. 


425]  ORGANIZATION,  PURPOSE,  EARLY  YEARS  113 

energetic ;  a  thinker  rather  than  an  actor.  It  was  his  duty 
to  keep  up,  both  through  the  press,  through  the  agencies, 
and  by  his  own  personal  visitations  to  various  parts  of  the 
country,  an  active  interest  in  the  subject  of  Colonization; 
to  superintend,  from  New  Orleans  to  Maine,  the  collection 
of  funds,  the  preparation  of  expeditions,  their  provisioning, 
and  the  collecting  of  emigrants;  the  general  supervision 
over  the  administration  of  the  colonial  agent  in  Liberia,  and 
the  impartial  and  judicious  treatment  of  so  dependent  a 
class  as  those  received  into  the  colony — all  this,  and  a  gen- 
eral supervision  of  the  government  of  a  colony  four  thou- 
sand miles  from  home,  a  colony  from  which  much  was 
hoped,  both  for  America  and  for  Africa. 

All  this  had  to  be  done,  and  the  Society  that  attempted  it 
was  supported  by  no  endowment,  no  financial  aid  from  the 
government,  except  some  very  inadequate  aid  from  several 
of  the  State  legislatures.  And  the  Society  was  not  even 
incorporated  until  nearly  the  end  of  the  period  of  which  we 
here  speak.  In  these  days  of  duplicators,  typewriters, 
stenographers,  fast  mail  trains,  and  a  highly  developed  pos- 
tal system,  we  probably  do  not  appreciate  the  burdens  that 
a  man  of  such  position  as  that  occupied  by  Gurley  had  to 
bear.  The  task  of  the  Abolitionists  was  to  agitate  the  sub- 
ject of  slavery  in  the  States  north  of  Mason  and  Dixon's 
line.  The  task  of  the  Colonizationist  was  to  conciliate  the 
North  and  the  South,  to  agitate  the  peaceable  and  gradual 
abolition  of  slavery  and  the  transportation  of  the  blacks  to 
Africa,  and  to  found  on  that  continent  a  republic  where 
freedom  could  be  actually  experienced  and  which  would  be 
a  model  for  the  rest  of  Africa. 

Reorganization  was  being  talked  of  as  early  as  1834.  In 
that  year  Leonard  Bacon  of  New  Haven,  Connecticut,  sug- 
gested that  the  active  management  of  the  Society  be  placed 
in  the  hands  of  five  or  seven  men  and,  to  prevent  the  possi- 
bility of  their  using  unwisely  their  power,  that  they  be  made 
subject  to  a  supervisory  body.  Reports  should  be  made  at 
each  annual  meeting,  and  at  these  meetings  representation 
8 


114  THE  AMERICAN    COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [426 

of  auxiliary  societies  should  be  in  proportion  to  the  amount 
of  funds  contributed  to  the  parent  treasury.188  Dissatis- 
faction was  further  evidenced,  at  the  annual  meeting  in 
1835,  when  a  delegate  from  the  New  York  Society  made  an 
effort  to  secure  the  election  on  the  Board  of  Managers  of 
four  additional  men,  two  of  them  aggressive  members  of  the 
Pennsylvania  Society,  and  by  an  effort  by  the  same  member 
to  secure  the  passage  of  resolutions  calling  on  the  Board  of 
Managers  to  reduce  their  office  expenditures.  These  efforts 
failed.189 

Whatever  accusations  are  made  concerning  the  distribu- 
tion of  seats  on  the  Board  of  Managers,  the  only  body,  prior 
to  1839,  which  had  an  active  part  in  shaping  the  policies  of 
the  Society,  there  can  be  no  complaint  made  on  the  score 
that  the  selection  of  those  officers  was  in  the  hands  of  the 
South  after  1836,  and  it  appears  there  is  no  evidence  that  at 
any  time  since  its  organization  in  1817  it  pursued  a  pro- 
slavery  policy.  In  1836  the  members  of  the  committee 
which  at  the  annual  meeting  nominated  the  Managers  was 
composed  of  two  delegates  from  New  York,  two  from  Vir- 
ginia, and  one  from  Ohio.190  For  1837,  all  five  members  of 
the  nominating  committee  were  from  the  Middle  and  West- 
ern States,  not  a  Southern  State  being  represented  on  the 
committee,191  although  the  appointments  were  made  by  the 
chairman,  C.  F.  Mercer,  of  Virginia.  The  Managers  elected 
for  1837  were  reelected  for  i838.192 

From  1837  to  the  time  when  the  reorganization  of  the 
parent  Society  was  effected,  the  New  York  and  Philadel- 
phia Societies  pursued  a  policy  calculated  either  to  kill  the 
older  organization  or  to  force  it  to  submit.  It  must  not  be 
forgotten  that  of  all  the  societies  in  the  United  States,  these 
two  were  able  to  command  the  largest  financial  resources. 
They  were  powerful  enough  to  secede  from  the  parent  So- 

188  Ibid.,  Bacon  to  Gurley,  New  Haven,  Conn.,  Jan.  3,  1834. 

189  African  Repository,  vol.  ii,  pp.  49-50. 

190  Ibid.,  vol.  xii,  p.  12. 

191  Ibid.,  vol.  xiii,  p.  35. 

192  Ibid.,  vol.  xiv,  p.  29. 


427]  ORGANIZATION,  PURPOSE,  EARLY   YEARS  11$ 

ciety  and,  in  cooperation  with  New  England,  establish  an 
organization  that  would  undoubtedly  have  alienated  the 
South  immediately  from  the  whole  scheme,  and  it  must  be 
repeated  that  the  orthodox  Colonizationist  was  never  a  sec- 
tionalist,  never  a  disunionist.  Between  1837  and  1839  these 
two  societies  jointly  presented  bills  for  the  payment  of 
which  the  parent  Society  was  in  no  sense  obligated  to  them, 
and  failed  to  redeem  pledges  made  by  them  to  the  parent 
Society  for  the  payment  of  a  percentage  of  their  collections 
.in  New  York  and  Pennsylvania.193  After  the  reorganiza- 
tion was  effected,  a  referee,  himself  a  citizen  of  New  York, 
decided  every  material  point  favorably  to  the  parent  So- 
ciety.19* 

In  1837  an  effort  was  made  among  the  New  York,  Penn- 
sylvania, and  Maryland  Societies  to  agree  upon  a  "  Consti- 
tution of  General  Government  for  the  -American  Settle- 
ments on  the  Western  Coast  of  Africa."  The  proposed 
plan  was  accepted  by  the  New  York  and  Pennsylvania  So- 
cieties but  rejected  by  that  of  Maryland.  It  was  then  pro- 
posed that  the  three  organizations  send  delegates  to  Phila- 
delphia for  the  purpose  of  effecting  a  union  among  them- 
selves. This  the  Maryland  Society  refused  to  do.  Instead, 
it  was  agreed  to  send  to  the  Washington  Society's  office  an 
"  Outline  of  a  new  Constitution  for  the  American  Coloniza- 
tion Society/'  which  should  replace  the  constitution  then  in 
force.  The  parent  Society  was  requested  to  send  copies  of 
the  proposed  changes  to  the  several  auxiliaries,  to  be  con- 
sidered by  them  and  voted  upon  at  the  annual  meeting  at 
the  end  of  i838.195  By  the  terms  of  this  proposed  consti- 
tution, the  Board  of  Managers  was  to  be  replaced  by  (i) 
a  Board  of  Directors,  and  (2)  an  Executive  Committee. 
By  the  old  constitution,  the  Managers  had  been  chosen  at 

188  Minutes  of  Board  of  Managers  of  American  Colonization  So- 
ciety, MS.,  April  6,  1837;  Sept.  28,  1837;  June  15,  1838;  October  16, 
1838. 

^ 19*  Minutes  of  Board  of  Directors  of  American  Colonization  So- 
ciety, MS.,  vol.  iii,  pp.  419-422;  African  Repository,  vol.  xv,  p.  19  ff. 

i»5  African  Repository,  vol.  xiv,  pp.  287-289. 


Il6  THE  AMERICAN    COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [428 

the  annual  meeting  by  a  vote  of  all  members  who  were  in 
attendance.  By  the  proposed  constitution,  the  Society  was 
to  be  composed,  not  of  individuals  as  units,  but  of  State 
societies  as  units.  The  Board  of  Directors  was  to  be  a  body 
composed  of  delegates  chosen  by  the  State  societies;  each 
such  society  contributing  not  less  than  one  thousand  dollars 
to  the  parent  treasury  to  be  entitled  to  one  delegate,  or 
member  of  the  Board  of  Directors.  Each  such  society 
having  under  its  care  a  colony  was  to  be  entitled  to  two 
members  of  the  Board;  any  two  or  more  such  societies 
uniting  in  the  support  of  a  colony,  comprising  at  least  three 
hundred  persons,  were  to  be  entitled  to  two  members,  each, 
on  the  Board. 

By  the  proposed  plan,  the  Board  of  Directors  was  to  meet 
annually,  when  they  were  to  appoint  an  executive  commit- 
tee, with  such  paid  officers  (ex-officio  members  of  the  ex- 
ecutive committee)  as  was  deemed  wise.  The  executive 
committee  was  thus  a  sort  of  subcommittee  of  the  Board 
and  was  subject  to  its  supervision  and  authority.  By  the 
proposed  plan,  each  auxiliary  society  was  to  be  allowed  to 
send  as  many  as  five  delegates  to  each  annual  meeting  of 
the  Society.196 

In  the  meantime  there  had  been  a  correspondence  among 
leading  Colonizationists  in  reference  to  the  wisdom  of  mak- 
ing so  radical  a  change  as  it  was  proposed  to  make.  Thomas 
Buchanan,  later  Colonial  Governor  of  Liberia  and  already 
a  leading  member  of  the  Pennsylvania  Society,  thought  that 
the  change  should  be  entire,  in  so  far  as  the  relations  be- 
tween the  several  auxiliary  societies  to  the  parent  organi- 
zation was  concerned.  "  I  would  have  a  general  Board  of 
Delegates  from  all  the  State  Societies  which  were  willing  to 
unite  for  that  purpose,  with  powers  of  legislation  for  the 
Colony,  the  appointment  of  officers,  etc.  But  without  the 
power  of  sending  out  emigrants  which  should  be  reserved 
to  the  State  societies."  He  favored  the  establishment,  "n 
Philadelphia  or  New  York,  of  an  executive  committee.  He 

186  Ibid.,  vol.  xiv,  pp.  287-289. 


429]  ORGANIZATION,  PURPOSE,  EARLY  YEARS  1 1/ 

thought  the  societies  that  had  established  independent  colo- 
nies in  Africa  should  surrender  their  jurisdiction  to  a  com- 
mon government  organized  by  the  parent  organization.197 

Elisha  Whittlesey,  of  Ohio,  thought  that  there  were 
changes  needed  in  the  organization,  "  but,"  said  he,  "  I  think 
we  should  correct,  and  not  annihilate."  Of  the  proposed 
board,  composed  of  representatives  from  the  State  societies, 
to  have  supervision  over  the  colonies  in  Africa,  he  thought : 
"  Such  a  Board  would  never  form,  or  if  at  all,  not  more 
than  once,  or  twice.  You  could  not  obtain  delegates  from 
Louisiana,  Tennessee,  and  Kentucky  who  would  meet  here 
or  at  the  East,  to  attend  to  the  concerns  of  the  Society."  It 
had  been  proposed  also  to  put  the  control  of  the  finances  of 
the  Society  in  the  hands  of  the  New  York  and  Pennsyl- 
vania societies.  Whittlesey's  comment  was :  "  Such  a  step 
would  cut  you  off  from  the  South  at  once..  We  want  to  in- 
spire more  confidence  in  the  South,  instead  of  lessening  that 
which  we  have."  As  to  the  location  of  the  central  office, 
for  there  was  a  movement  to  make  Philadelphia  or  New 
York  the  central  office,  he  thought  it  should  be  located  "  at 
the  seat  of  the  General  Government,  on  common,  neutral 
ground.  Here  the  Managers  are  easily  collected  together, 
and  they  better  understand  how  to  harmonize  the  discordant 
elements  at  the  North  and  at  the  South  than  those  who  re- 
side elsewhere.  The  New  York  and  the  Pennsylvania  So- 
ciety must  not  leave  us  either.  Whatever  is  wrong  must 
be  corrected,  and  then  we  must  have  more  zeal  and  en- 
ergy."198 

The  views  of  Gurley  were  very  similar  to  those  of  Whit- 
tlesey. He  called  attention  to  the  fact  that  the  movement 
for  reorganization  was  distinctly  a  movement  of  the  Penn- 
sylvania and  New  York  Societies;  that  whatever  criticism 
they  made  of  the  administration  of  affairs  by  the  Board  of 
Managers  came  with  poor  grace  from  the  very  societies 

197  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Thomas  Buch- 
anan to  Samuel  Wilkeson,  Philadelphia,  May  10,  1838. 

198  Ibid.,  Whittlesey  to  Wilkeson,  Washington,  June  3,  1838. 


Il8  THE   AMERICAN    COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [43O 

which  had  sanctioned  those  elections;  that  the  energy  of 
the  parent  organization  had  been  impaired  by  the  refusal  of 
these  two  societies,  the  most  able  to  contribute,  to  redeem 
their  pledges;  that  the  Managers,  far  from  profiting  by 
their  connection  with  the  Board,  had  often  assumed  volun- 
tarily the  responsibility  for  large  amounts  which,  had  they 
been  called  on  to  make  good,  would  have  weighed  heavily 
upon  them.  He  favored  an  early  settlement  of  the  rela- 
tions between  the  auxiliary  and  the  parent  societies,  but 
thought  that  the  central  office  should,  by  all  means,  remain 
at  the  national  capital.  "To  destroy  the  parent  Board," 
said  he,  "is,  in  my  judgment,  to  ruin  the  cause  at  the 
South."199  Joseph  Gales,  a  North  Carolinian  by  birth,  who 
since  1834  had  been  the  treasurer  of  the  parent  Society,  put 
the  blame  for  a  considerable  part  of  the  financial  distress 
of  the  Society  directly  upon  the  New  York  and  Pennsyl- 
vania societies,  through  their  refusal  to  meet  the  pledges 
made  by  them  at  the  time  of  the  agreement  by  which  they 
pursued  an  independent  policy.  And  this,  he  thought,  was 
the  chief  cause  of  the  widespread  criticism  among  the  So- 
ciety's friends.20' 

During  this  discussion  of  the  changes  desirable  in  the 
parent  society,  Judge  Samuel  Wilkeson  of  Buffalo,  New 
York,  and  one  who  may,  with  considerable  justice,  be  called 
the  father  of  Buffalo,  was  invited  by  the  Board  of  Mana- 
gers to  become  general  agent  for  the  Society,  with  power  to 
commission,  instruct,  or  remove  agents,  as  he  thought  nec- 
essary. To  him  was  committed  also  the  supervision  of  the 
finances.  In  short,  he  was  made  practically  dictator  of  the 
Society's  affairs  in  the  United  States.201  Wilkeson  accepted 
the  task,  magnanimously  refusing  compensation  until  the 
Society  should  be  free  from  debt.202  He  threw  himself  into 

199  Ibid.,  Gurley  to  Wilkeson,  Washington,  June  4,  1838. 

200  Ibid.,  Gales  to  Wilkeson,  Washington,  Aug.  4,  1838. 

201  African  Repository,  vol.  xv,  pp.  6-7 ;  Minutes  of  Board  of 
Managers  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Dec.,  1838. 

202  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Wilkeson  to 
Gurley,  New  York,  July  7,  1838. 


43 1  ]  ORGANIZATION,  PURPOSE,  EARLY  YEARS  119 

the  work  with  an  energy  uncommon  among  men  but  char- 
acteristic of  himself.  Possessed  of  none  of  the  suavity  with 
which  Gurley  made  friends  wherever  he  went,  inclined  to 
underestimate  the  inspirational  side  of  a  movement  based 
upon  public  opinion,  he  lived  in  Western  New  York,  made 
money,  got  things  done,  was  a  chief  among  pioneers,  and 
suffered  from  the  gout. 

Hardly  had  Wilkeson  begun  his  duties  in  the  Coloniza- 
tion cause,  when  Cresson  began  to  complain  about  the  need 
for  reform.  "I  hope/'  wrote  he,  "you  will  dismiss  the 
idlers  at  Washington  next  month  and  give  the  friends  of 
the  cause  new  hopes  thereby  that  the  mice  in  the  treasury 
will  not  eat  up  all  the  meal."209  Here,  as  elsewhere,  there 
was  an  element  of  value  in  Cresson's  criticism,  but  it  was 
far  overstated.  The  Board  might  probably  have  done  well 
to  have  dispensed  with  the  services  of  one  or  two  of  its  office 
force,  after  the  cause  came  under  such  formidable  discour- 
agement, but  Wilkeson  himself  found  that  the  public  had 
been  misled  in  its  belief  that  much  further  economy  was 
practicable.204  The  new  general  agent  went  to  work  with 
a  will,  however,  and  reported  to  the  Managers  in  December, 
1838: 

I  have  found  it  very  difficult  to  obtain  such  agents  as  are  re- 
quired. ...  In  some  sections  of  the  country  the  hostility  of  aboli- 
tionists is  dreaded.  The  cause  of  colonization  has  been  so  long 
neglected,  that  the  societies  heretofore  organized  have  everywhere 
been  suffered  to  die,  and  many  men  formerly  warm  colonizationists 
.  .  .  are  unwilling  to  encounter  the  difficulties  now  presented.  Very 
many  believe  that  the  low  state  to  which  colonization  [has  come]  is 
owing  to  the  impracticability  of  carrying  it  on  by  private  charity. 
.  .  .  Very  many  others  .  .  .  believe  that  some  radical  change  in 
the  organization  and  management  ...  is  necessary  to  its  success. 
Even  in  those  sections  .  .  .  which  have  been  abandoned  to  the  aboli- 
tionists ...  I  have  found  that  a  large  proportion  of  the  people  are 
glad  to  hear  once  more  of  colonization  and  hail  it  as  a  great  con- 
servative principle  that  will  save  our  country,  and  elevate  the  colored 
man.*05 

At  the  annual  meeting  in  January,  1839,  the  interest  was 

208  Ibid.,  Cresson  to  Wilkeson,  Woodstock,  Vermont,  Nov.  28, 1838. 

20*Ibid.,  Wilkeson  to  Gales,  New  York,  Nov.  16,  1838;  Nov.  30, 
1838;  Gales  to  Wilkeson,  Washington,  Nov.  28,  1838. 

205  Letters  of  Board  of  Managers  of  American  Colonization  So- 
ciety, MS.,  Dec.  10,  1838. 


I2O  THE  AMERICAN   COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [432 

intense.  The  New  York,  New  Jersey,  and  Pennsylvania 
Societies  sent  delegations  that  numerically  reached  the 
maximum  allowed  by  the  rules.  Besides,  Virginia  had  a 
full  and  able  delegation,  her  representatives  being  C.  F. 
Mercer,  Wm.  C.  Rives,  James  Garland,  Henry  A.  Wise,  and 
Abel  P.  Upshur.  Of  the  total  number  of  delegates,  thirty- 
one,  New  York,  New  Jersey,  and  Pennsylvania  sent  seven- 
teen, Virginia  six,  arid  the  West  four,  the  District  of  Co- 
lumbia sending  four.208  The  reason  for  the  full  delegations 
is  obvious.  New  York,  New  Jersey  and  Pennsylvania  had 
come  to  bring  about  radical  changes  in  the  organization. 
These  changes  undoubtedly  constitute  the  first  official  rec- 
ognition, of  consequence,  of  one  section  as  opposed  to  an- 
other, in  the  constitution  of  the  Society.  They  constitute 
the  first  step  made  by  Colonizationists  in  the  estrangement 
of  the  upper  South  and  the  Southwestern  States.  That 
some  changes  were  needful  for  the  very  life  of  the  Society 
is  obvious.  That  those  changes  took  the  direction  they  did 
is  altogether  regrettable. 

In  the  first  discussion,  at  the  annual  meeting,  there  was 
no  agreement  between  the  delegates  from  the  North  Middle 
States  and  the  Virginians.  A  committee,  composed  of  two 
Southerners  and  four  from  New  York  and  Pennsylvania, 
reported  a  compromise,  in  which  the  Virginians  took  what 
they  could  get,  and  it  was  adopted  by  the  representatives 
and  became,  in  name,  the  amended,  but  in  fact,  the  new 
constitution.  The  changes  adopted  were  not  so  radical  as 
those  recommended  by  the  Maryland,  Pennsylvania,  and 
New  York  societies  in  1837,  but  they  were  quite  radical 
enough.207  The  name  and  the  object  of  the  Society  were, 
in  the  revised  instrument,  stated  to  be  the  same  as  in  the 
old;  but  that  was  about  all.  It  may  be  well  to  compare  it 
with  the  original  constitution,  on  the  one  hand,  and  with  the 
proposed  one,  on  the  other. 

(i)  The  name  and  professed  object  of  the  Society  re- 
main the  same  in  all  three. 

206  African  Repository,  vol.  xv,  p.  19  ff. 

207  See  above. 


433]  ORGANIZATION,  PURPOSE,  EARLY  YEARS  121 

(2)  By  the  old  constitution,  the  parent  Society  was  a 
society  composed  of  individuals;  by  the  proposed  consti- 
tution it  was  to  be  a  federation  of  auxiliary  societies ;  by  the 
instrument  actually  adopted  it  was  to  partake  of  the  nature 
of  both.     Every  citizen  of  the  United  States  who  paid  an- 
nually as  much  as  one  dollar  into  the  treasury  was  to  be 
considered  a  member;  but  membership  on  its  Board  of 
Directors,  the  actual  governing  power  of  the  Society,  was 
confined  to   societies  contributing  certain  fixed  amounts. 
Every  society  contributing  not  less  than  $1000  was  entitled 
to  two  directors  of  the  Board;  every  society  having  under 
its  care  a  colony  was  entitled  to  three  delegates ;  every  two 
or  more  societies  jointly  maintaining  a  colony  of  not  fewer 
than  three  hundred  settlers,  was  entitled  to  three  delegates. 
Any  individual  contributing  as  much  as  $1000  to  the  parent 
treasury  was  entitled  to  membership  for  life  on  the  Board 
of  Directors. 

(3)  By  the  old  constitution,  the  Society  was  to  meet  an- 
nually ;  by  the  proposed  instrument,  the  Board  of  Directors 
was  to  meet  annually ;  by  that  adopted,  both  the  Society  and 
the  Board  of  Directors  were  to  meet  annually. 

(4)  By  both  the  proposed  and  the  new  constitutions,  any 
State  Colonization  Society  maintaining  a  colony  in  Liberia 
was  given  the  right  to  appropriate  its  funds  to  the  mainte- 
nance of  such  colony. 

(5)  By  the  new  instrument,  all  sums  paid  into  the  treas- 
ury of  the  parent  Society  were,  after  the  payment  of  ex- 
penses for  collecting  and  after  paying  a  certain  portion  of 
the  existing  debt,  to  be  applied  to  the  benefit  of  the  colony 
of  Monrovia,  where  the  Colonial  Governor  was  to  reside.208 

To  understand  how  radical  was  this  change,  and  how 
completely  it  deprived  the  South  of  even  a  respectable  voice 
in  the  management  of  an  enterprise  in  which  it  was  asked 
and  urged  to  make  continued  and  important  contributions, 
it  is  sufficient  to  call  attention  to  the  fact  that  the  very  first 
Board  of  Directors,  after  the  adoption  of  the  new  consti- 

208  African  Repository,  vol.  xv,  p.  19  ff. 


122  THE  AMERICAN   COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [434 

tution,  was  composed  of  eight  members  from  the  States 
north  of  Maryland,  two  from  those  south  of  the  District  of 
Columbia,  two  from  the  District  of  Columbia,  and  two  from 
Ohio.209  A  whole  section,  itself  the  very  center  of  opera- 
tions of  the  Society,  deprived  of  any  effective  representa- 
tion in  its  proceedings,  could  not  be  expected  to  continue  to 
exhibit  an  active  interest.  Indeed,  when  one  takes  into 
consideration  the  sectional  bitterness  of  the  time,  it  is  re- 
markable how  long  some  of  the  Southern  States  did  lend 
their  support  to  the  movement  that  was  now  in  northern 
hands.  For  years  Virginia,  Mississippi  and  Louisiana  did 
important  service  for  the  Society.  But  from  1839  there  is 
evident  a  new  spirit,  a  spirit  that  must  not  be  attributed 
altogether  to  the  rise  of  cotton  production  but  also  to  the 
loss  of  a  hearing  in  the  councils  of  Colonization. 

But  it  may  be  asked,  why  did  not  the  Southern  States 
pay  into  the  treasury  enough  to  entitle  them  to  an  equal 
representation  with  the  Middle  States  ?  Simply  because  of 
the  two  facts :  ( i )  the  South  was  not  able  to  make  contri- 
butions equal  to  those  of  the  more  prosperous  section,  and 
(2)  no  matter  how  many  slaves  a  Southern  slaveholder 
gave  away  for  emigration  to  Africa,  the  South  was  not 
thereby  given  credit  for  a  single  dollar  in  its  representa- 
tion among  the  directors.  The  reorganizers  of  the  Society 
committed  a  capital  blunder  in  ignoring  this  important  fact. 
And  then  there  was  that  other  consideration,  to  which  Whit- 
tlesey  had  already  called  attention.  New  York  and  Penn- 
sylvania and,  for  that  matter,  all  New  England,  were  so 
much  nearer  the  seat  of  the  Society  than  were  the  Southern 
States  that  where  members  of  the  Board  of  Directors  came 
from  the  States  they  represented  the  North  would  invaria- 
bly outnumber  the  South  in  the  number  of  those  in  attend- 
ance. It  is  sufficient  here  to  say  that  the  estrangement  of 
the  South  was  not  due  altogether  to  economic  changes  in 
that  section.  The  South,  at  least  a  part  of  it,  began  to  lose 
interest  in  the  American  Colonization  Society  before  it  b^:- 

soe  Ibid.,  vol.  xv,  p.  «7. 


435]  ORGANIZATION,  PURPOSE,  EARLY  YEARS  123 

gan  to  lose  interest  in  the  cause  of  colonization.  By  1840 
both  Louisiana  and  Mississippi  were  seriously  contemplat- 
ing action  independent  of  the  American  Colonization  So- 
ciety, and  the  basis  of  their  position  was  that  good  faith  to 
the  South  required  it.210  By  1843  McLain,  Secretary  of 
the  parent  Society,  wrote: 

More  than  half  the  South  look  upon  us  as  a  co.  of  abolitionists 
only  called  by  another  name.211  And  by  April,  1852,  Alabama  had 
organized  a  Colonization  Society  entirely  independent  of  the  Ameri- 
can Colonization  Society,  and  because  there  was  in  the  minds  of 
many  an  impression  that  the  Am.  Col.  Society  partook  too  much  of 
the  abolition  spirit  to  receive  their  countenance  and  support.212 

Since  1830  there  had  arisen  a  great  need  for  the  incor- 
poration of  the  Society.  Several  bequests  had  been  lost, 
and  some  had  not  been  made,  because  of  the  fact  that  the 
Society  was  not  a  corporate  body.  After  one  or  two  efforts 
to  secure  a  charter  of  incorporation  from  Congress,  all  of 
which  ended  in  failure,  General  Walter  Jones  declaring  that 
a  debate  in  Congress  over  the  charter  of  the  Society  would 
have  divided  and  agitated  that  body  more  than  would  the 
proposal  to  recharter  the  United  States  Bank,213  the  Mary- 
land legislature  granted  it  a  charter  in  i83i.214  This  was 
not  altogether  satisfactory.  During  1837  Clay  made  two 
efforts  to  secure  in  Congress  a  more  satisfactory  charter, 
but  again  it  was  refused.  Finally,  the  Maryland  legisla- 
ture, in  1837,  granted  the  amended  charter.215 

A  word  more  as  to  the  finances  of  the  Society.  Of  those 
who,  in  1838,  were  contributors  on  the  plan  of  Gerrit 
Smith,  that  is,  who  subscribed  one  hundred  dollars  per  year 
for  a  period  of  ten  years,  two  were  from  Maine,  one  from 
Vermont,  two  from  Massachusetts,  one  from  Connecticut, 
one  from  Rhode  Island,  five  from  New  York,  two  from 

210  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  F.  Knight  to 
Wilkeson,  Aug.  I,  1840,  No.  704. 

11  Ibid.,  McLain  to  Dodge,  Feb.  27,  1843,  No.  720. 
212  Journal  of  Executive  Committee  of  American   Colonization 
Society,  MS.,  Apr.  16,  1852. 

3  The  Liberator,  Feb.  15,  1834. 

214  Minutes  of  Board  of  Managers  of  American  Colonization  So- 
ciety, MS.,  Feb.  15;  1837. 
21«  Ibid.,  Mar.  30,  1837. 


124  THE  AMERICAN   COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [436 

New  Jersey,  four  from  Pennsylvania,  one  from  Delaware; 
sixteen  from  Virginia,  one  from  South  Carolina,  four  from 
Mississippi,  seven  from  Louisiana,  three  from  Maryland, 
two  from  the  District  of  Columbia,  and  one  from  Ohio.218 
The  total  expenditures  of  the  Society  to  November  13, 1838, 
were  $379,644.1 5. 21T  By  1839  the  total  debt  of  the  Society 
was  estimated  by  Wilkeson  at  approximately  $7O,ooo.218 

It  was  not  a  bright  day  for  colonization,  in  December, 
1838;  with  a  heavy  debt,  hardly  an  agent  actively  engaged 
in  the  work,  a  difference  of  opinion  between  the  northern 
and  southern  branches  of  the  Society  as  to  the  best  means 
of  giving  it  efficiency,  and  a  North  and  West  that  had  been 
invaded  and,  if  not  conquered,  at  least  dumfounded  by  the 
accusations  of  the  Abolitionists.  This  was  enough,  but  this 
was  not  all.  When  the  New  York  delegates  went  back  to 
report  they  found  that  Society  unwilling  to  ratify  their 
agreement  to  the  amended  constitution.  Wilkeson,  who 
labored  earnestly  for  the  cooperation  of  the  Pennsylvania 
and  New  York  Societies  wrote,  in  May,  1839:  "A  negotia- 
tion between  the  Emperor  of  Russia  and  the  States  of  Hol- 
land in  the  sixteenth  century  could  not  be  more  diplomati- 
cally ceremonious  than  that  between  your  two  societies."210 
Difficulties  were  real  when  a  man  of  his  indomitable  will 
admitted,  "  I  confess  I  feel  discouraged.  .  .  .  Can  there  be 
any  organization  that  will  unite  all  friends  of  the  cause  in 
support  of  the  Am.  Col.  Society?  If  not,  the  friends  of  the 
cause  ought  to  know  it."220  But  there  were  brighter  days 
ahead. 

216  African  Repository,  vol.  xiv,  back  cover. 

217  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Gales  to  Wilke- 
son, Washington,  Nov.  14,  1838. 

218  Ibid.,  Wilkeson  to  Ker,  Washington,  July  25,  1840.    No.  680. 

219  Ibid.,  Wilkeson  to  Rev.  Hope,  May  9,  1839. 

220  Ibid.,  Mar.  28,  1840,  no.  119. 


CHAPTER  III 

AMERICAN  COLONIZATION  AND  GARRISONIAN  ABOLITION. 

The  bitterest  opposition  Colonization  ever  encountered 
came  from  the  Abolitionists  of  William  Lloyd  Garrison's 
school.  Next  to  these,  its  fiercest  enemies  were  the  slave- 
holders of  the  Southeastern  States.  One  who  turns  the 
pages  of  Garrison's  Liberator  for  the  years  1831  to  1835, 
will  be  struck  by  the  fact  that  in  some  issues  more  space  was 
given  to  tearing  down  the  influence  of  the  Colonization  So- 
ciety than  was  used  in  direct  opposition  to  the  institution 
of  slavery.  Henry  Clay  told  the  truth  when,  in  1838,  he 
said :  "  The  roads  of  Colonization  and  Abolition  lead  in  dif- 
ferent directions,  but  they  do  not  cross  each  other,"1  but 
no  more  hostile  denunciation  was  ever  used  in  depicting  the 
crimes  of  slaveholders  than  was  used  in  characterizing  the 
Colonizationist  leaders.  This  is  all  the  more  surprising 
when  the  fact  is  known,  and  it  is  a  fact,  that  those  very 
Colonizationists  with  whom  Garrison  came  in  contact  were 
as  truly  opposed  to  slavery  as  Garrison  himself.  Elijah 
Paine,  one  of  the  foremost  citizens  of  Vermont  and  for 
years  President  of  the  State  Colonization  Society,  was  as 
earnest  an  advocate  of  emancipation  as  any  Abolitionist  in 
the  North,2  but  The  Liberator  made  no  distinctions. 

In  the  struggle  for  supremacy  the  Garrisonians  took  the 
offensive.  The  opposition  began  with  them  and  continued 
until  Colonization  journals  refused  longer  to  take  notice  of 
Abolition  speeches  or  articles.8  Between  1831  and  1840 
the  opposition  often  took  the  form  of  direct  meetings  in 

1  African  Repository,  vol.  xiv,  pp.  17-18. 

2  Ibid.,  vol.  xv,  pp.  44-48. 

8  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  W.  McLain  to 
Hon.  Edw.  Storrs,  December  30,  1841,  No.  494;  McLain  to  Samuel 
Elliott,  vol.  iv,  No.  1425. 

"5 


126  THE  AMERICAN    COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [438 

debate.4  Frequently  after  the  debate  a  vote  would  be  taken 
to  ascertain  the  sentiments  of  the  audience.  When,  in  1835, 
Gurley  made  a  tour  of  New  England,  there  was  no  dearth 
of  challengers  among  the  Garrisonians.  At  Boston  he 
chanced  into  a  session  of  one  of  their  conventions  and  had 
hardly  taken  his  seat  when  a  Garrisonian  leader  arose  and 
moved  a  resolution  declaring  the  principles  of  the  American 
Colonization  Society  to  be  "unrighteous,  unnatural,  pro- 
scriptive,  and  the  attempt  to  give  permanency  to  the  insti- 
tution [of  slavery],  a  fraud  on  the  credulity  and  an  outrage 
on  the  intelligence  of  the  public,"  and  challenging  any  per- 
son present  to  defend  the  Society.  Gurley  arose,  and  the 
result  was  a  two  days'  debate.6  Proceeding  to  Concord, 
New  Hampshire,  he  found  another  convention  in  session, 
and  here  also  he  was  drawn  into  a  discussion  which  ended 
quite  favorably  to  Colonization,  if  we  are  to  judge  by  the 
subscriptions  received  from  prominent  men  of  the  State  at 
a  meeting  held  a  day  or  two  later  in  the  same  city  and  re- 
sulting from  the  debate.  Among  the  subscribers  were  the 
governor,  an  ex-governor,  Judge  Upham,  and  many  mem- 
bers of  the  legislature.6  These  are  but  illustrations  of  what 
was  going  on  throughout  the  North  and  West  between  Colo- 
nization agents  and  radical  Abolitionists. 

It  must  not  be  forgotten  that  there  were  two  distinct 
classes  of  Abolitionists:  (i)  moderates  and,  (2)  Garriso- 
nians. This  classification  was  well  known  in  the  North, 
and  the  distinction  is  so  important  for  our  present  pur- 
poses, for  reference  in  this  chapter  is  made  almost  wholly 
to  the  Garrisonians,  that  attention  is  here  called  to  it.  It 
will  be  profitable  to  consider  briefly  an  important  point  in 

4  African  Repository,  vol.  ix,  p.  218;  vol.  x,  pp.  125-126;  Letters 
of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Gurley  to  Fendall,  Boston, 
June  i,  1835. 

6  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Gurley  to  Fen- 
dall, Boston,  June  1, 1835 ;  Minutes  of  Board  of  Managers  of  Ameri- 
can Colonization  Society,  MS.,  vol.  iii,  p.  190  ff. 

6  Minutes  of  Board  of  Managers  of  American  Colonization  So- 
ciety, MS.,  vol.  iii,  p.  193.  Letters  of  American  Colonization  So- 
ciety, MS.,  Gurley  to  Fendall,  Boston,  June  n,  1835. 


439]  COLONIZATION  AND  ABOLITION  I2/ 

connection  with  the  origin  of  the  Garrisonian  group  and  of 
the  Colonizationists. 

Garrison  founded  his  group  upon  a  sectional  sentiment; 
Colonization  was  founded  upon  a  national  sentiment.  Gar- 
rison's sowing  was  of  the  wind  and,  as  we  shall  come  to  see 
hereafter,  his  reaping  was  of  the  whirlwind.  Colonization- 
ists have  been  accused  of  many  unworthy  motives,  but 
never  yet  have  they  been  accused  of  ever  having  sown  a 
seed  of  disunion  and  civil  strife.  It  was  born  out  of  a  de- 
sire to  unite  the  North  and  the  South  in  the  settlement  of 
the  negro  problem.  Garrison  was  determined  to  free  the 
slaves  at  once,  whether  or  not  the  result  was  the  disruption 
of  the  Union;  Colonizationists  were  determined  to  forego 
immediate  emancipation,  for  the  sake  of  accomplishing  both 
ultimate  emancipation  and  the  preservation  of  the  Union. 
This  is  the  very  heart  of  the  distinction  between  the  creeds 
of  Garrisonians  and  Colonizationists.  As  to  ulterior  aims 
and  motives,  in  the  origins  and  progress  of  the  two  organi- 
zations, the  paramount  aim  of  Garrison  has  been  univer- 
sally admitted  to  be  the  immediate  and  unconditional  eman- 
cipation of  all  the  slaves  in  the  United  States.  The  sincerity 
of  his  aims  has  never  been  seriously  questioned.  Unfor- 
tunately, and  thanks  to  the  vituperation  of  the  Garrisonians 
themselves,  the  motives  of  the  Colonizationists  have  been 
widely  misrepresented  since  1831.  It  is  the  purpose  of  this 
study  to  set  forth  the  true  aims  of  orthodox  Colonization- 
ists, or,  from  another  point  of  view,  to  demonstrate  that 
their  aims  were  as  sincerely  expressed  as  sound  policy  would 
admit,  and  that,  where  motives  were  concealed,  they  were 
concealed  in  order  to  retain  the  good  will  of  the  slaveholder 
in  order  to  secure  the  freedom  of  his  slaves. 

However,  it  is  desired  here  chiefly  to  set  forth  and  com- 
pare the  methods  used  by  the  Garrisonians  and  the  members 
of  the  American  Colonization  Society  in  their  relations  with 
each  other  and  with  the  Southern  slaveholders,  and  to  set 
forth  also  the  results  of  the  methods  pursued  by  each. 

A  favorite  method  employed  by  Garrison  to  prejudice  the 


128  THE  AMERICAN   COLONIZATION  SOCIETY  [440 

North  against  the  Colonization  movement  was  to  take 
speeches  made  by  Clay,  or  articles  written  by  Gurley  and 
others  and,  by  a  process  of  garbling,  create  in  the  minds  of 
readers  of  the  Abolitionist  newspapers  an  entirely  erroneous 
view  of  the  attitude  of  Colonizationists  toward  the  whole 
subject  of  slavery.  The  Colonizationists  desired  to  appeal 
to  all  sections  of  the  Union.  They,  therefore,  were  careful 
not  to  alienate  the  sympathies  of  slaveholders.  An  impor- 
tant fact  which  Garrison  either  failed  to  appreciate  or  con- 
sistently ignored  was  that  the  Colonization  Society  desired 
far  more  earnestly  to  abolish  slavery  than  it  expressed  in 
its  official  journal.  It  would  have  been  much  more  difficult 
for  him  to  make  a  plausible  garbled  account  of  its  attitude, 
as  expressed  in  all  its  official  records  and  private  corre- 
spondence— and  only  here  could  be  found  expressed  its  true 
attitude  on  that  question — than  to  compile  such  an  account 
from  the  African  Repository.7  A  striking  example  of  the 
method  employed  is  contained  in  Garrison's  Thoughts  on 
African  Colonization,  page  149.  In  an  effort  to  prove  Dr. 
Caldwell,  one  of  the  most  active  founders  of  the  Coloni- 
zation Society,  a  proponent  of  slavery,  Garrison  offers  the 
following  quotation: 

The  more  you  improve  the  condition  of  these  people,  the  more  you 
cultivate  their  minds,  the  more  miserable  you  make  them  in  their 
present  state.  You  give  them  a  higher  relish  for  those  privileges 
which  they  can  never  attain,'and  turn  what  you  intend  for  a  blessing 
into  a  curse.  No,  if  they  must  remain  in  their  present  situation, 
keep  them  in  the  lowest  state  of  ignorance  and  degradation.  The 
nearer  you  bring  them  to  the  condition  of  brutes,  the  better  chance 
do  you  give  them  of  possessing  their  apathy. 

It  is  true  that  Dr.  Caldwell  made  the  remark  as  quoted ; 
but  he  followed  it  immediately,  and  as  the  expression  of  his 
own  view,  with  the  following  sentiment,  which  Garrison 
omitted  from  his  quotation : 

Surely  Americans  ought  to  be  the  last  people  on  earth  to  advo- 
cate such  slavish  doctrines,— to  cry,  peace  and  contentment  to  those 

'For  an  example  of  Garrison's  method,  see  both  The  Liberator 
for  December  8,  1832,  pp.  193-194,  and  African  Repository,  January, 
1833,  pp.  346-347.  See  also  African  Repository,  first  article,  March, 
1833. 


44 1  ]  COLONIZATION  AND  ABOLITION  1 29 

who  are  deprived  of  the  blessings  of  civil  liberty.  Those  who  have 
so  largely  partaken  of  its  blessings — who  know  so  well  how  to  esti- 
mate its  value,  ought  to  be  foremost  to  extend  it  to  others. 

When  Garrison  was  called  to  account  for  this  utter  per- 
version of  the  views  of  Dr.  Caldwell,  he  admitted  he  had 
not  read  Dr.  Caldwell's  remarks,  but,  at  the  same  time, 
when  he  should  have  been  content  with  doing  Caldwell, 
already  in  his  grave,  the  justice  of  a  frank  confession  of  his 
own  serious  blunder,  he  made  an  effort  to  prove  by  other 
extracts  and  quotations,  that  he  had,  after  all,  not  done  that 
leader  injustice  in  an  estimate  of  his  views.  In  the  latter 
attempt  he  ingloriously  failed.8  As  a  matter  of  fact,  both 
Francis  Scott  Key  and  Caldwell  had  been  active  in  securing 
the  liberty  of  negroes  in  the  District  of  Columbia  taken 
illegally  into  slavery.9 

A  method  similar  to  the  above,  employed  by  The  Libera- 
tor, was  that  of  publishing  as  evidence  of  the  proslavery 
sentiment  in  the  Colonization  Society,  divided  votes  at  an- 
nual meetings,  although  these  votes  were  expressions  of 
policy  alone,  and  were  in  no  true  sense  an  expression  of  the 
views  of  the  organization  upon  the  subject  of  slavery.10  In 
a  number  of  instances,  accusations  made  had  no  foundation 
whatever  in  fact.11  Garrison  himself,  while  on  a  tour  of 
England  in  advocacy  of  his  cause,  stated  that  the  American 
Colonization  Society 

originated  with  those  who  held  a  large  portion  of  their  fellow- 
creatures  in  worse  than  Egyptian  bondage;  that  it  was  generally 
supported  by  them ;  and  that  it  was  under  their  entire  control — that 
not  one  of  its  officers  and  managers  had  emancipated  his  slaves,  and 
sent  them  to  Liberia  .  .  .  that  it  maintained  that  no  slave  ought  to 
receive  his  liberty,  except  on  condition  of  instant  banishment  from 
the  country.  .  .  . 

It  was  "the  apologist  and  friend  of  American  slavehold- 
ers."12 These  accusations  are  so  sweeping  in  their  scope 

8  The  Liberator,  Nov.  2,  1833;  Jesse  Torrey,  A  Portraiture  of 
Domestic  Slavery  in  the  United  States,  pp.  86-87,  Philadelphia,  1817. 

9  Torrey,  pp.  49-52. 

10  The  Liberator,  March  2,  1833;  April  6,  1833;  Sept.  21,  1833. 
"African  Repository,  vol.  ix,  pp.  201-203;  United  States  Tele- 
graph, July  24,  18.33. 

12  The  Liberator,  October  19,  1833. 


I3O  THE  AMERICAN    COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [442 

that  a  refutation  of  them  here  would  require  needless  repe- 
tition. But  if  the  positions  taken  in  this  study  have  been 
successfully  maintained,  the  motives  of  Colonizationists 
were  utterly  misstated  by  Garrison. 

The  columns  of  The  Liberator  were  at  times  self-contra- 
dictory. For  instance,  the  issue  for  September  21,  1833, 
contained  a  reprint  which  required  for  insertion  the  whole 
of  the  first  and  part  of  the  second  page ;  it  was  an  account 
of  the  maltreatment  of  the  Northerner,  Rev.  J.  B.  Pinney, 
whom  the  South  Carolinians  erroneously  thought  had  come 
to  Columbia  in  advocacy  of  Colonization.  And  on  the  next 
column  was  another  reprint  which  contained  an  insinuation 
that  the  Colonizationists  were  in  collusion  with  South  Caro- 
lina slaveholders. 

Again,  there  was  circulated  about  1839,  by  the  Abolition- 
ists, a  so-called  Authentic  Narrative  of  James  Williams,  an 
American  Slave,  which  set  forth  the  cruel  treatment  re- 
ceived by  southern  slaves  at  the  hands  of  their  owners. 
Upon  an  examination  into  the  authenticity  of  the  Authentic 
Narrative,  it  was  found  that  the  pamphlet  was  a  fabrication, 
and  it  was  repudiated  by  the  antislavery  committee  which 
made  the  investigation.18 

During  a  session  of  the  Methodist  General  Conference,  in 
Baltimore,  an  ultra-Abolitionist  delegate  presented  an  Abo- 
lition petition  containing  eleven  or  twelve  hundred  signa- 
tures. When  investigation  was  made  it  was  found  that 
"scores  of  names  were  signed  twice,  and  many  .  .  .  were 
.  .  .  forgeries,  or  declared  to  be  so  by  the  parties.  Hun- 
dreds were  ascertained  to  have  been  signed  to  a  temperance 
memorial,  and  had  been  surreptitiously  appended  to  this. 
Whole  families  .  .  .  were  subscribed,  who  declare  they  had 
never  seen  the  memorial.  .  .  ,14  Negroes  returning  from 
Liberia  and  bringing  accounts  entirely  untrustworthy  were 
employed  by  Garrisonians  to  set  forth  the  "  true  "  condition 
of  affairs  in  Africa.15 

13  African  Repository,  vol.  xv,  pp.  161-163. 
*  Ibid.,  vol.  xvi,  pp.  350-351. 

"Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  B.  M.  Palmer 
to  Gurley,  Charleston,  S.  C,  May  26,  1834. 


443]  COLONIZATION   AND  ABOLITION 

In  1842  an  Abolitionist  lecturer  of  Vermont  assured  his 
auditors  that  the  Colonizationists  were  throwing  money 
away,  having  already  made  away  with  more  than  one  hun- 
dred million  dollars  since  1817.  Upon  protest  from  a  cler- 
gyman who  was  in  the  audience,  the  lecturer  assured  his 
hearers  that  his  statement  was  drawn  from  the  official  rec- 
ords of  the  Society.  As  a  matter  of  fact  he  had  overstated 
his  figures  something  over  ninety-nine  and  a  half  million 
dollars.16  An  Indiana  Colonization  agent  reported  that  in 
that  State  the  Abolitionists  were  using  as  an  argument 
against  the  Society  the  statement  that  "the  men  who  are 
engaged  in  taking  free  blacks  to  Liberia  bring  back  two  or 
three  slaves  for  every  black  taken  out."17  Judge  Samuel 
Wilkeson,  General  Agent  of  the  Society,  wrote  to  a  Ver- 
mont Colonizationist : 

The  abolitionists  in  many  parts  of  the  country  are  becoming  quiet. 
You  observe  that  they  have  made  some  statements  which  you  believe 
untrue  but  have  not  the  means  of  correcting  them.  Those  who  con- 
trol the  abolition  press  generally  are  destitute  or  reckless  of  truth, 
making  statements  of  which  they  have  not  the  evidence  of  truth,  or 
which  they  know  to  be  false.  For  instance,  Mr.  Garrison  published 
me  last  fall  as  a  large  slaveholder  in  Florida.  I  called  on  his  agent 
and  assured  him  that  I  never  owned  a  slave,  and  requested  him  to 
contradict  the  charge,  which  instead  of  being  done,  the  falsehood 
has  gone  the  rounds  of  every  abolition  paper  in  the  Union.18 

Besides  these  direct  misstatements  of  fact,  the  Garrison- 
ians  made  sweeping  assertions  that  are  utterly  incapable  of 
proof,  but  which  cannot  be  refuted  except  by  a  considera- 
tion of  the  whole  history  of  the  Society.  Garrison  charged, 
for  instance,  that  the  American  Colonization  Society  "is 
pledged  not  to  oppose  the  system  of  slavery  " ;  "  apologizes 
for  slavery  and  slaveholders";  "is  nourished  by  fear  and 
selfishness";  "aims  at  the  utter  expulsion  of  the  blacks"; 
"  is  the  disparager  of  the  free  blacks  " ;  "  deceives  and  mis- 
leads the  nation."19 

When  the  debt  of  the  Colonization  Society  was  published 

16  Ibid.,  Dr.  A.  Proudfit  to  Whittlesey,  New  York,  September, 
1842. 

17  Ibid.,  B.  T.  Kavanaugh  to  McLain,  Indianapolis,  April  18,  1846. 

18  Ibid.,  Wilkeson  to  J.  P.  Fairbanks,  June  21,  1839. 

19  African  Repository,  vol.  ix,  pp.  105-109. 


132  THE   AMERICAN    COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [444 

in  the  February  Liberator,  1835,  that  periodical  was  exult- 
ant, exclaiming:  "MENE,  MENE,  TEKEL,  UPHARSIN.  Debt 
of  the  Handmaid  of  Slavery,  $46,000."  In  the  same  issue, 
of  eight  and  one-half  feet  in  columns  of  printed  matter  on 
the  first  page,  all  but  five  inches  is  devoted  to  tirades  against 
the  Society,  an  important  part  of  it  being  made  up  of  gar- 
bled quotations  from  Colonization  leaders.20  Cresson  writes 
from  Glasgow  of  C.  Stuart,  confederate  and  warm  co- 
worker  with  Garrison  while  Stuart  was  in  America,  that 
the  latter  denounced  all  those  who  used  West  India  sugar 
as  "doomed  to  hell,  with  damnation  for  their  portion."21 
An  Indiana  agent  reported  that  the  Abolitionist  candidate 
for  governor  of  that  State,  who  was  also  a  member  of  the 
Indiana  Supreme  Court,  in  an  attack  upon  Colonization 
spoke  "  in  a  most  loose,  vulgar,  and  abusive  manner  inso- 
much that  the  ladies  were  driven  off."22  Examples  of  the 
immoderate,  misleading  and  untrue  statements  of  Mr.  Gar- 
rison's paper  are  the  following:  "We  are  becoming  daily 
more  versed  in  the  corruption  of  the  advocates  of  the  Amer- 
ican Colonization  Society.  With  all  their  insolence,  they 
are  dastardly."  "The  records  of  the  Colonization  Society 
are  obvious  exhibitions  of  deceitfulness."  "As  it  is  at 
present  organized,  the  American  Colonization  Society  can- 
not justly  make  any  pretension  to  justice  or  mercy,  with 
more  plausibility  than  they  could  who  brought  the  natives 
of  Congo  from  their  own  land."23  Commenting  on  the 
debt  of  the  Colonization  Society,  the  same  publication  ex- 
claimed : 

We  have  not  room  for  all  the  speeches  that  were  delivered,  but 
the  following  extracts  [which,  by  the  way,  were  very  misleading 
summaries  of  those  delivered  at  the  annual  meeting]  show  that  the 
Genius  of  Contradiction  presided  on  the  occasion,  assisted  by  Hy- 
pocrisy, Falsehood,  Desperation  and  Folly.  The  days  of  the  Society 
are  numbered.  Glory  to  God  in  the  highest  !2* 

20  Ibid.,  vol.  xi,  p.  57 ;  vol.  x,  pp.  356-360 ;  The  Liberator,  Feb.  22, 
1834. 

21  Letters   of   American   Colonization    Society,   MS.,   Cresson  to 
Gurley,  Glasgow,  Mar.  15,  1833. 

22  Ibid.,  Kavanaugh  to  McLain,  Indianapolis,  April  30,  1846. 

23  The  Liberator,  May  18,  1833. 
*<  Ibid.,  Feb.  8,  1834. 


44 S ]  COLONIZATION    AND   ABOLITION  133 

One  would  think  that  the  editor  would  have  hesitated  in 
his  sweeping  characterizations,  for  in  the  same  paper  is 
contained  the  admission: 

Were  numbers  necessary  to  the  success  of  the  Colonization  So- 
ciety? It  has  enrolled  upon  its  list,  the  high  and  the  low,  the  rich 
and  the  poor,  all  classes  of  people,  in  multitudinous  gatherings  and 
multiform  varieties.  Did  it  need  the  sanctity  of  religion?  What 
theological  institution,  what  religious  sect,  what  presbytery,  synod, 
general  assembly,  conference,  or  church,  what  eminent  divine  or 
deacon,  what  religious  periodical  or  newspaper,  has  it  not  until 
recently  counted  approvingly  on  its  side?  Did  it  need  political 
favor?  It  has  been  appropriated  by  all  parties.  ...  In  short,  in 
its  ranks  have  stood,  hand  in  hand,  the  Presbyterian  and  the  Quaker, 
the  Episcopalian  and  Baptist,  the  Methodist  and  Unitarian,  the  Uni- 
versalist  and  Infidel — the  freeholder  and  slaveholder.  .  .  ,26 

It  seems  not  to  have  occurred  to  the  editor  that  an  organi- 
zation which  could  boast  of  such  a  host  of  supporters  was 
not  to  be  condemned  in  terms  of  wanton  ridicule  and  sar- 
castic vituperation. 

A  further  method  of  the  Garrisonians  was  to  draw  in 
lurid  colors  utterly  untrustworthy  pictures  of  slavery  as  a 
system,  pictures  which  fired  the  minds  of  the  New  Eng- 
lander  and  exasperated  the  Southerner,  who  was  perfectly 
acquainted  with  the  system.28  On  a  par  with  these  were 
the  unqualified  statements  of  Garrison  that  (i)  slavehold- 
ing  is  in  all  cases  sinful,  (2)  it  should  be  immediately  pro- 
hibited, (3)  "If  it  were  evident  that  only  by  a  short  delay, 
he  could  be  better  prepared  to  receive  the  boon  of  liberty, 
still  the  slave  ought  to  be  a  free  man  now.  .  .  "21 

The  Colonization  agent  had  to  endure  not  only  this  whole- 
sale condemnation  of  the  cause  in  which  he  labored  but  also, 
in  many  cases,  personal  calumny.  Elliot  Cresson,  on  a  mis- 
sion to  England  for  the  promotion  of  the  Colonization 
cause,  wrote  from  Edinboro: 

In  no  place  has  the  A[nti]  Sflavery]  party  had  recourse  to  more 
abject  means  of  insult.  ...  In  these  assaults,  for  myself,  supported 
by  the  consciousness  of  my  high  mission,  I  care  not;  but  if  you  do 
not  vindicate  yourselves  thro'  me,  and  meet  the  libels  of  the  A.  S. 
Party,  by  prompt  letters  .  .  .  the  cause  must  suffer.  Let  them 


25  Ibid.,  Dec.  13,  1834. 

26  Ibid.,  May  3,  1834,  p.  71. 

27  Ibid.,  March  7,  1835. 


134  THE   AMERICAN   COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [446 

know  that  I  enjoy  your  entire  confidence,  and  that  every  penny  re- 
ceived, is  religiously  devoted  to  legitimate  purposes — for  to  check 
the  current  of  benevolence,  I  found  it  whispered  about  that  I  was 
without  authority  from  you — disbursing  your  funds  for  my  own 
purposes,  and  any  other  means  as  miscreants  deemed  most  likely  to 
circumvent  me.28 

Indeed,  he  became  restive  under  the  continued  vexations  to 
which  he  was  subjected.  He  could  not  hear  from  Coloni- 
zation headquarters  frequently  enough  to  keep  up  such  a 
defensive  as  desired  and,  in  exasperation,  he  asked,  "  How 
can  I  fight  (for  fight  I  must)  if  I  have  neither  weapons  or 
ammunition?  Must  I  like  the  spider  spin  them  out  of  my 
own  unaided  self?"29 

So  reckless  had  the  Garrisonians  become  in  their  deter- 
mination to  gain  their  ends  that  they  resorted  to  the  frank 
statement  of  sentiments  which,  but  for  the  burning  question 
of  slavery,  would  have  branded  them  for  all  time  as  traitors 
to  their  country.  When  the  discussion  between  this  coun- 
try and  Great  Britain  over  the  northeast  boundary  between 
the  United  States  and  Canada  was  at  its  height,  an  Ameri- 
can negro,  Redmond,  who  was  a  Garrisonian  lecturer  and 
was  speaking  in  Scotland,  openly  advocated  war  between 
the  United  States  and  Great  Britain,  even  at  the  risk  of 
the  defeat  of  his  own  country,  and  for  the  reason  that  it 
would  bring  about  the  emancipation  of  the  slaves  at  the 
South.30  The  British  Garrisonians  were  in  accord  with 
this  view.  One  of  their  newspapers  gave  this  exaggerated 
view  of  the  slave  system  in  America : 

The  horrors  of  the  slave  system,  as  pursued  in  the  Southern 
States,  are  unutterable;  nothing  that  the  wildest  imagination  can 
conceive  surpasses  the  cruelties  inflicted  on  the  wretched  negro  vic- 
tims ;  and  if  it  were  in  our  power  to  stir  up  the  spirit  of  the  slaves 
to  rebel  against  the  heartless  planters  ...  we  would  use  that  power, 
though  all  America  was  thrown  into  disorder,  and  presented  one 
wide  field  of  bankruptcy  and  ruin.81 

A  contributor  to  Eraser's  Magazine,  taking  his  data  from 

28  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Cresson  to  Gur- 
ley,  Edinboro,  Mar.  19,  1833. 

29  Ibid.,  Cresson  to  Gurley,  Adelphi,  June  6,  1833 ;  London,  Octo- 
ber 6,  1831. 

80  27th  Cong.,  3d  sess.,  H.  Rept.  No.  283,  p.  1026. 

81  Ibid.,  pp.  1026-1027. 


447]  COLONIZATION   AND   ABOLITION  135 

a  recent  publication  of  the  American  Abolitionists,  urged 
upon  the  British  the  high  moral  duty  to  declare  war  against 
the  United  States,  with  the  ultimate  aim  of  freeing  the 
slaves  in  the  South.  Taking  the  Abolitionist  statements  at 
their  face  value,  the  writer  urged  that  America  "holds 
nearly  three  millions  of  unoffending  human  creatures  in 
the  most  cruel  bondage ;  in  a  thraldom  infinitely  worse  than 
Egyptian,  Turkish,  or  Sclavonian.  In  fact,  we  doubt  if  the 
annals  of  the  human  race  afford  an  example  of  any  system 
of  oppression  at  all  approaching  to  that  which  is  proved 
...  to  exist  in  America."  The  dissolution  of  the  Union 
was,  then,  highly  desirable,  both  for  the  security  of  Great 
Britain's  possessions  and  for  the  abolition  of  slavery  in  the 
United  States.  Immediately  upon  the  declaration  of  such 
a  war,  if  it  were  made  clear  that  it  was  to  be  prosecuted  as 
a  war  for  emancipation,  the  free  blacks,  of  Jamaica  would 
lend  their  aid  at  once.  "In  one  morning  a  force  of  ten 
thousand  men  might  be  raised  in  this  quarter.  ...  In 
three  weeks  .  .  .  the  entire  south  would  be  in  one  con- 
flagration."32 

The  North  Carolina  Quaker,  Jeremiah  Hubbard,  who 
was  willing  to  go  as  far  as  any  man  in  a  rational  program 
for  the  abolition  of  slavery,  made  these  observations  upon 
Garrisonian  methods: 

I  would  give  thee  a  little  specimen  of  his  style  and  manner  of 
writing ;  in  his  opinion  of  the  Colonization  Society,  he  says  : — "  The 
superstructure  of  the  Colonization  Society  rests  upon  the  following 
pillars,  i.  Persecution.  2.  Falsehood.  3.  Cowardice.  4.  Infidelity. 
If  I  do  not  prove  the  Colonization  Society  to  be  a  creature,  without 
heart,  without  brains,  eyeless,  unnatural,  hypocritical,  relentless,  un- 
just, then  nothing  is  capable  of  demonstration!!!"  His  language 
to  slaveholders,  or  of  slaveholders  is,  "  They  are  hypocrites,  man- 
stealers ;  and  such  as  hold  offices  in  the  United  States,"  he  says, "  are 
guilty  of  corrupt  perjury,  and  unless  they  repent,  will  have  their 
part  in  the  lake  that  burns  with  fire  and  brimstone."  This  kind  of 
language  is  not  at  all  calculated  to  make  good  impressions  on  the 
minds  of  slaveholders,  even  of  those  of  whom  it  may  be  true,  and 
it  is  utterly  false  as  respects  many  who  hold  slaves — they  would  be 
very  glad  to  have  it  in  their  power  to  put  their  slaves  in  a  better 
situation.  .  .  .•• 

82  Eraser's  Magazine,  London,  April,  1841,  pp.  494-502. 
»»  African  Repository,  vol.  x,  p.  37  ff. 


136  THE  AMERICAN   COLONIZATION   SOCIETY 

Hubbard  was  Clerk  of  the  yearly  meeting  of  Friends  of 
North  Carolina,  a  member  of  both  the  Colonization  Society 
and  an  Abolition  Society,  though  not  of  Garrison's  school, 
a  leader  among  a  group  of  seven  or  eight  thousand  Quakers 
of  North  Carolina,  who  had  contributed  thousands  of  dol- 
lars toward  the  Colonization  Society,  had  fought  slavery 
for  upwards  of  fifty  years,  had  for  forty  years  repeatedly 
memorialized  the  legislature  for  permission  to  conscientious 
slaveholders  to  manumit  their  slaves,  had  assisted  about  one 
thousand  slaves  to  seek  their  liberty  in  a  free  State.  And 
Hubbard's  comment  is:  "After  all  this,  by  the  above  posi- 
tive denunciation  we  are  indirectly  assailed  by  the  coloni- 
zation persecutors  as  liars,  cowards,  infidels,  without  heart, 
without  brains,  eyeless,  unnatural,  hypocritical,  unjust. 
Such  language,  my  brethren,  is  not  calculated  to  conquer 
enemies,  gain  friends,  soften  hard  hearts,  or  convince  infi- 
dels, even  if  it  were  true."34 

The  fierceness  and  boldness  of  these  Abolitionist  attacks 
were  not  without  tremendous  effect.  Some  of  the  most 
consistent  Colonizationists  of  New  England  were  startled 
by  their  "revelations."  Ezra  S.  Gannet  was  one  of  this 
class.  He  had  read  statements  made  in  Boston  by  Thomas 
C.  Brown,  a  former  colonist  who,  having  become  dis- 
gruntled because  of  the  failure,  up  to  this  time,  of  the  Colo- 
nization Society  to  pay  a  claim  held  against  them  for 
lumber  that  Brown  had  shipped,35  had  been  employed  as  a 
Garrisonian  lecturer  to  "inform"  the  New  Englanders  of 
conditions  in  Liberia  and  of  the  attitude  of  Colonizationists 
toward  slavery.  Gannet  was  wise  enough  to  write  to  Colo- 
nization headquarters  for  their  statement  of  the  facts  about 
which  Brown  had  spoken.86  The  reply  was  satisfactory 
and  Gannet  continued  his  relations  with  the  Colonization- 
ists.37 In  his  reply,  he  refers  to  the  "  most  unmerited  and 

8*  Ibid.,  vol.  x,  pp.  214-215. 

85  Letters   of   American   Colonization   Society,   MS.,   Grimke   to 
Gurley,  1854. 

86  Ibid.,  Gannet  to  Gurley,  Boston,  June  19,  1834. 

87  Ibid.,  Nov.  12,  1834. 


449]  COLONIZATION    AND   ABOLITION 

shameful  abuse  from  violent  Anti- Slavery "  writers,  to 
which  the  Society  and  its  agents  had  been  subjected,  and  of 
the  "extravagance  and  intemperance  of  Mr.  Garrison." 
The  anti-slavery  agitator,  Dr.  Thomas  Hodgkin,  of  London, 
wrote  to  the  American  delegates  to  the  Anti-Slavery  Con- 
vention held  in  that  city  in  1840:  "I  admit  that  you  have 
completely  succeeded  in  drawing  a  repulsive  picture  of  the 
Society,  but  I  do  not  admit  that  it  gives  a  fair  idea  of  the 
reality."38 

A  group  of  Colonizationist  students  from  Western  Re- 
serve College  wrote  Gurley  in  1832  of  the  effect  The  Lib- 
erator had  already  had  in  the  College  before  Garrison  had 
been  publishing  it  two  years.  Before  its  appearance  upon 
the  reading  tables  of  that  institution  the  student  body  had 
expressed  no  doubt  of  the  sincerity  of  the  Colonization 
movement.  By  1832  not  only  students  but  the  faculty  were 
enlisted  in  two  opposing  groups.  One  group  wrote : 

We  had  always  supposed  .  .  .  that  the  Colonization  Society  was 
friendly  to  human  rights,  was  the  avowed  enemy  of  slavery,  an 
uncompromising  foe  of  the  oppressor;  and  that  its  ultimate  design 
and  tendency  was  to  free  the  captive.  .  .  .  We  had  supposed  these 
to  be  its  claims,  and  that  these  were  incontrovertible.  But  they  are 
flatly  denied  in  this  same  land  of  Ohio,  and  the  institution  de- 
nounced, as  wanting  even  the  common  sanction  of  benevolent 
design  !3» 

It  was  thus  throughout  New  England  and  the  West.  If 
Garrison  caught  the  ear  of  some  of  the  most  prominent  men 
of  those  sections  of  the  Union,  it  is  not  difficult  to  picture  the 
effect  his  clear  cut,  unmistakable  charges  had  upon  the  minds 
of  those  who  accepted  without  deep  reflection  the  sentiments 
they  heard  or  read  upon  a  topic  so  absorbing  as  that  of  negro 
slavery.  From  Portland,  Maine,  the  report  from  the  Colo- 
nizationist agent  came,  that  "a  prodigious  current  turned 
after"  Garrison.40  The  Secretary  of  the  Society,  after  a 

88  African  Repository,  vol.  xvi,  pp.  311-313. 

89  Letters  of  American   Colonization   Society,   MS.,   Students  of 
Western  Reserve  College,  Hudson,  Ohio,  to  Gurley,  October  29, 
1832. 

40  Ibid.,  Cummings  to  J.  N.  Danforth,  Portland,  Maine,  February 
14,  1832. 


138  THE   AMERICAN    COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [450 

tour  of  New  England  during  the  summer  of  1834,  reported 
evidences  of  a  distinct  change  of  sentiment  in  New  England 
unfavorable  to  the  Society.  Coming  as  it  does  from  him, 
the  following  statement  is  not  without  value,  as  showing  the 
view  taken  by  Gurley  of  the  motives  and  hopes  of  Coloni- 
zationists.  He  says: 

Yet  in  the  light  of  clearest  evidence,  that  the  American  Coloniza- 
tion Society  was  designed  and  has  been  sustained  with  the  view  of 
affording  means  and  motives  for  the  voluntary,  peaceful  and  entire 
abolition  of  slavery;  that  its  moral  influence  favorable  to  emanci- 
pation, has  been  and  is  operating  most  extensively  and  powerfully 
at  the  South,  the  anti-slavery  men  of  the  North  denounce  it  as  the 
friend  and  ally  of  slavery,  and  attempt  its  overthrow  with  more 
zeal  and  effort,  if  possible,  than  even  that  of  slavery  itself.  Be- 
cause the  friends  of  colonization  are  indisposed  to  pursue  a  course 
which  must,  in  their  opinion,  put  in  imminent  jeopardy  the  peace 
and  safety  of  a  large  portion  of  the  country,  endanger  the  security 
and  even  the  very  existence  of  the  Federal  Government,  because 
they  believe  that  the  consent  of  the  South  is  indispensable  to  any 
plan  for  the  abolition  of  slavery,  they  are  denounced  as  enemies  to 
the  colored  race  and  to  the  cause  of  Liberty.41 

There  is  a  good  deal  of  the  prophetic  in  this  utterance. 

If  there  was  any  distinctive  feature  of  William  Lloyd 
Garrison's  efforts  from  1831  to  1839,  it  was  the  alienation 
of  New  England  and  the  West  from  the  spirit  of  coopera- 
tion with  the  South,  in  the  effort  to  get  rid  of  slavery,  to 
the  spirit  of  antagonism  against  the  South,  in  the  effort  to 
force  that  section  to  abolish  slavery.  If  the  methods  of 
Garrison  during  those  years  had  any  inevitable  result,  it 
was  that  of  replacing  nationalism  by  sectionalism.  A  gen- 
eration had  not  passed  away  before  the  surmises  of  Gurley 
had  become  regrettable  fact.  Eight  years  after  the  tour 
upon  which  comment  has  just  been  made,  he  was  in  New 
England  again;  and  this  time  he  found  churches  closed 
against  him  and  all  those  who  worked  with  him ;  he  found 
the  New  England  public  apathetic  toward  the  essentially 
national  efforts  of  his  Society;  he  found  the  clergy  either 
cowed  into  silence  by  the  pronounced  views  of  their  congre- 
gations or  else  themselves  victims  of  the  adroit,  if  unscru- 
pulous, lecturers,  editors,  and  agitators  who  visited  every 

41  African  Repository,  vol.  x,  pp.  120^-139. 


45 1]  COLONIZATION   AND   ABOLITION  139 

New  England  and  Western  town.42  By  1840  Garrison  had 
accomplished  very  well  one  thing —  the  consolidation  of 
New  England  and  the  then  Northwest  in  an  aggressive  sec- 
tionalism. Those  individuals  from  the  North  who  had  vis- 
ited the  South,  or  who  had  resided  there,  understood  that 
the  denunciations  of  Garrison  were  based  upon  a  picture 
of  a  system  of  slavery  that,  as  a  system,  had  no  existence 
save  in  the  mind  of  that  leader.43  But,  unfortunately,  those 
were  not  the  days  of  railroad  and  telegraph  lines,  and  Gar- 
rison and  the  masses  whom  he  influenced  knew  little  of  the 
real  system  of  slavery  that  existed  in  the  South.44 

Public  opinion  unified  and  sectional  passion  excited,  the 
next  step  in  the  program  of  the  Garrisonians  was  to  enter 
politics.  Hereafter  the  fitness  of  a  candidate  was  to  be 
judged  by  his  agreement  or  disagreement  with  their  views 
on  the  subject  of  slavery.  This  step  had  been  reached  be- 
fore the  end  of  the  thirties.45  It  was  the  most  dangerous 
step  Abolitionists  ever  took.  It  is  always  dangerous  for 
any  considerable  section  to  test  the  fitness  of  those  political 
leaders  who  sit  as  the  nation's  lawmakers  by  their  position 
upon  any  issue  that  is  essentially  sectional.  By  1840  the 
New  Hampshire  Garrisonians  had  so  far  developed  their 
scheme  of  coercion  as  to  determine  to  unsettle  all  clergy- 
men in  the  State  who  would  not  subscribe  to  their  views.46 
If  we  will  remember  that  the  mass  of  the  people  of  New 
England  knew  little  of  the  system  of  slavery  as  it  actually 
existed  at  the  South,  and  also  that  it  was  these  same  people 
who  elected  or  refused  to  elect  those  candidates  and  those 
clergymen  who  offered  their  services  to  the  State  and  to 
the  Church,  we  shall  better  understand  why  the  very  leaders 

42  Journal  of  Executive  Committee  of  American  Colonization  So- 
ciety, MS.,  Nov.  25,  1842,  pp.  294-307 ;  Letters  of  American  Coloni- 
zation Society,  MS.,  Danforth  to  Gurley,  December  21,  1832;  S.  M. 
Worcester  to  Gurley,  Amherst  College,  November  5,  1834. 

« Ibid.,  G.  D.  Abbot  to  Gurley,  New  York,  Jan.  15,  1833. 

44  Ibid.,  Amos  A.  Phelps,  Andover  Theological  Seminary,  Jan. 
15,  1828. 

45  African  Repository,  vol.  xv,  p.  19  ff. 

46  Letters   of  American  Colonization   Society,  MS.,  Prof.  O.  P. 
Hubbard  to  Wilkeson,  Dartmouth  College,  May  5,  1840. 


I4O  THE   AMERICAN    COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [452 

in  New  England  thought  were  anti-Garrisonians  in  1832, 
while,  in  1840,  many  of  them  had  gone  over  to  that  faith. 

It  must  not  be  supposed  that  William  Lloyd  Garrison  and 
The  Liberator,  alone,  conquered  the  Colonization  spirit  of 
New  England  and  the  Northwest.  There  were  other 
speakers  and  other  papers,  many  of  them.  It  seems  that  at 
the  Granville,  Ohio,  postoffice  in  1836,  there  were  being 
taken,  or  were  sent,  more  than  three  hundred  Abolition 
publications  and  only  one  publication  of  the  Colonization- 
ists.47  The  President  of  the  Granville  Colonization  Society 
wrote  that  of  six  hundred  and  ninety  periodicals,  religious, 
scientific,  professional,  and  Abolition,  emanating  from  one 
hundred  and  twenty  presses,  there  was  but  one  copy  of  the 
African  Repository  and  no  other  Colonization  paper  taken ; 
also,  that  "Anti-Slavery  lecturers  have  for  several  years 
past  visited  us  every  few  weeks  or  months;  sometimes  re- 
maining a  week  or  two  and  lecturing  as  often  as  they  could 
collect  a  congregation."48  Gurley  in  1842  estimated  the 
proportion  of  Colonization  to  Abolition  lecturers  to  be  about 
one  to  one  hundred.49  At  any  rate,  there  had  come  over 
some  prominent  Colonizationists  a  radical  change  of  senti- 
ment, and  some  Colonization  leaders  became  such  opponents 
of  the  Society  as  to  out-Garrison  Garrison. 

One  of  these  was  Arthur  Tappan  who,  by  1833,  came  to 
the  opinion*  that  "  The  Colonization  Society  is  a  device  of 
Satan  and  owes  its  existence  to  the  single  motive  to  per- 
petuate slavery."50  And  Gerrit  Smith,  who  had  given  thou- 
sands of  dollars  to  the  Society  and  had  expressed  his  dis- 
pleasure with  the  methods  of  Garrison,  was  a  radical  of  the 
radicals  by  1838.  He  had  been  asked  to  contribute  to  the 
erection  of  a  Methodist  Church  in  New  Orleans.  He  re- 
fused to  do  so,  and  stated  his  reason  as  follows : 

Suppose  I  were  invited  to  contribute  to  the  cost  of  erecting  a 
heathen  temple,  could  I  innocently  comply  with  the  request?  .  .  . 

47  Ibid.,  Seven  Wright  to  Gales,  Granville,  Ohio,  March  23,  1836. 

48  Ibid.,  W.  S.  Richards  to  Gurley,  Granville,  Ohio,  March  28,  1838. 
48  Ibid.,  Gurley  to  R.  S.  Finley,  Dec.  14,  1842,  No.  489. 

60  Ibid.,  Tappan  to  Gurley,  New  York,  June  26,  1833. 


453]  COLONIZATION   AND  ABOLITION  14! 

Now,  I  take  it  for  granted,  that  the  Religion  which  is  to  be  preached 
in  the  "  place  of  worship  "  which  you  invite  me  to  assist  in  prepar- 
ing is  the  Religion  of  the  South;  and  I  put  it  to  your  candor, 
whether  it  is  not,  therefore,  fairly  to  be  considered  as  an  idolatrous 
"place  of  worship."51 

Besides  the  direct  attacks  made  by  the  Garrisonians  upon 
the  Colonization  Society  and  those  who  were  interested  in 
it,  that  party  worked  indirectly  but  very  effectively  to  the 
prejudice  of  Colonization  by  discouraging  the  blacks  from 
offering  to  emigrate  to  the  colony.  The  word  "  emigra- 
tion "  was  replaced  by  the  words  "  banishment,"  "  expatria- 
tion," and  so  on.  Although  the  records  have  been  exam- 
ined, not  a  single  case  of  involuntary  exportation  has  been 
revealed ;  but  the  use  of  those  terms  kept  many  a  negro 
from  offering  to  go  to  Liberia.  The  free  blacks,  who  at 
one  time  hailed  with  delight  the  opportunity  of  returning  to 
the  land  of  their  fathers,  began  to  adopt  resolutions  in  oppo- 
sition to  the  Society,  and  after  the  thirties  there  was  a 
marked  indisposition  among  them  to  emigrate  to  the  colony.52 

In  the  South  probably  the  most  effective  argument  against 
the  Colonization  Society  was  that  it  was  but  a  form  of  Abo- 
litionism ;  in  the  North  and  Northwest,  that  its  purpose  was 
to  "  rivet  the  chains  of  the  slave."  The  persistence  of  those 
who  used  these  contradictory  arguments  ought  to  be  well 
nigh  conclusive  of  the  motives  of  Colonizationists.  But 
hitherto  it  has  never  been  so.63  Henry  Clay  expressed  the 
position  of  the  Society  when  he  said:  " Both  objections  can- 
not be  founded  in  truth.  Neither  is."54  The  proslavery 

51  African  Repository,  vol.  xiv,  pp.  48-49. 

62  Carey,  p.  2 ;  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS., 
Burr  to  Gurley,  Richmond,  Va.,  January  27,  1834;  African  Reposi- 
tory, vol.  xvi,  p.  114;  Speech  of  Edward  Everett  at  Anniversary  of 
American  Colonization  Society,  January  18,  1853;  Manuscript  Divi- 
sion, Library  of  Congress,  Massachusetts  Broadsides,  24th  Anti- 
Slavery  Bazaar. 

68 African  Repository,  vol.  i,  pp.  341-343 ',  vol.  vi,  p.  iff.;  vol.  ix, 
pp.  228-229;  vol.  xii,  p.  298;  vol.  xiv,  pp.  17-18;  vol.  xix,  p.  152. 

54  No  more  complete  refutation  of  the  charges  of  the  Abolition- 
ists, who  declared  that  the  Colonization  Society  forged  the  chains 
of  the  slaves,  can  be  given  than  the  following  references  to  private 
letters  written  by  leading  agents  of  the  Society.  They  contain  what 
ought  to  be  a  final  answer  to  those  who  made,  or  continue  to  make, 
those  charges.  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Bir- 


142  THE  AMERICAN    COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [454 

slaveholders,  and  it  is  a  pity  Garrison  could  not  realize  that 
there  were  actually  antislavery  slaveholders  in  the  South, 
ought  to  have  understood  that  an  organization  that  was  as 
persistently  opposed  by  the  Abolitionists  as  was  the  Coloni- 
zation Society,  could  not  be  considered  an  advocate  of  a 
general  and  immediate  abolition  of  slavery ;  and  the  Aboli- 
tionists ought  to  have  understood  that  an  organization  that, 
in  1832,  could  not  maintain  an  agency  in  either  Georgia  or 
South  Carolina,  was  hardly  to  be  convicted  of  collusion 
with  slaveholders.55 

Colonizationists  believed  that  a  general,  immediate,  and 
unconditional  emancipation  of  all  the  slaves  in  the  Union 
was  impracticable  and  undesirable:  impracticable  (i)  be- 
cause there  was  no  constitutional  right  of  the  federal  gov- 
ernment to  enact  a  general  emancipation  provision,  (2)  be- 
cause the  States  alone  having  the  right  to  pass  emancipation 
measures  would  do  so  only  as  the  public  sentiment  of  each 
slave  State  became  favorable  to  emancipation,  (3)  because 
public  sentiment  in  the  slave  States  was  not  yet  favorable ; 
undesirable  (i)  because  it  was  believed  that  three  millions 
of  negro  slaves  set  free  at  one  time  would  be  unable  to  care 

ney  to  Gurley,  Huntsville,  Alabama,  July  12,  1832;  Mechlin  to  Gur- 
ley,  Liberia,  February  28,  1833;  Cresson  to  Gurley,  Mar.  15,  1833; 
Danforth  to  Gurley,  Boston,  December  28,  1832;  J.  H.  Cocke  to 
Gurley,  Norfolk,  January  14.  1833;  Gallaudet  to  Gurley,  Hartford, 
March  24,  1833 ;  Finley-Birney  to  Gurley,  New  Orleans,  April  13, 
1833;  Gurley  to  Fendall,  Boston,  August  3,  1835;  T.  B.  Balch  to 
Wilkeson,  Locust  Hill,  October  II,  1839;  Balch  to  Wilkeson,  New 
Baltimore,  November  20,  1839;  J.  D.  Mitchell  to  Cresson,  Liberty, 
December  28,  1839;  Henkle  (see  Cresson  to  Wilkeson),  February 
27,  1840;  Ker  (see  Cresson  to  Wilkeson),  Miss.,  March  12,  1840; 
W.  McKenney  to  Wilkeson,  Greensboro,  N.  C.,  November  6,  1840; 
Mrs.  M.  B.  Blackford  to  Gurley,  Va.,  January  28,  1843 ;  C.  W.  An- 
drews to  McLain,  Virginia,  Mar.  27,  1843;  Tracy  to  Gurley,  Boston, 
May  8,  1843;  Pinney  to  McLain,  April  5,  1845;  D.  L.  Carroll  to 
McLain,  New  York,  July  5,  1845. 

No  effort  has  been  made  to  continue  these  references  beyond  the 
year  1845,  for  it  is  believed  that  there  is  no  doubt  about  the  position 
of  the  Colonization  Society  after  that  time.  Nor  is  the  above  a 
complete  list.  It  is  deemed,  however,  sufficient  to  set  forth  the  true 
view  of  the  Society  on  the  subject  of  slavery. 

68  Minutes  of  Board  of  Managers  of  American  Colonization  So- 
ciety, MS.,  March  7,  1832;  March  12,  1832;  March  26,  1832;  April 
9,  1832;  July  it,  1832. 


455]  COLONIZATION   AND  ABOLITION  143 

for  themselves,  and  would  be  more  wretched  than  under  a 
system  of  slavery,  (2)  because  the  so-called  free  negro  was 
not  in  any  true  sense  free,  and  it  was  believed  would  not 
become  really  free  until  he  was  taken  back  to  his  native 
country  and  there,  under  the  supervision  of  sympathetic 
governors,  was  taught  self-sustenance  and  self-government, 
(3)  because  of  the  danger  of  a  race  war  in  the  States  of 
the  lower  South.  They  recognized  slavery  to  be  an  evil. 
The  remedy  for  it  they  believed  to  be  gradual  emancipation, 
made  practicable  through  (i)  cooperation  between  the  dif- 
ferent sections  of  the  Union,  (2)  the  education  of  slave- 
holders, (3)  and  the  transportation  of  those  manumitted  or 
emancipated.  They  hoped  and  believed  that  such  States 
as  Maryland,  Virginia,  Kentucky,  and  Tennessee  would 
enact  general  emancipation  measures  within  a  period  of  time 
not  very  remote,  and  that  with  these  States  free,  the  rest 
would  follow,  as  the  success  of  emancipation  and  transpor- 
tation combined  was  demonstrated.  They  hoped  to  exert 
a  powerful  moral  influence  in  favor  of  emancipation,  but 
were  opposed  to  the  use  of  illegal  means  or  means  whose 
result  might  be  to  involve  the  sections  in  civil  war,  or  bring 
about  the  dissolution  of  the  Union.  The  gradual  abolition 
of  slavery  was  not  to  be  an  incidental  object  of  the  Society. 
It  was  to  be  one  of  the  two  direct,  distinct,  and  primary 
objects :  ( i )  to  give  real  freedom  to  the  nominally  free 
American  negro,  by  returning  him  to  his  native  land  and 
there  encouraging  his  highest  development,  (2)  to  exert 
the  most  powerful  moral  pressure  consistent  with  national 
peace  and  unity  in  favor  of  an  emancipation  as  rapid  as 
practicable,  and  both  universal  and  absolute.56 

From  its  origin,  the  Society  used  with  eagerness  every  op- 
portunity to  secure  the  liberation  of  slaves  by  offering  to 
transport  them  to  the  colony,  unless  the  condition  of  its 
treasury  was  such  that  it  could  not  afford  the  expenditure. 

86  African  Repository,  vol.  vii,  pp.  49,  176,  200-201,  314;  vol.  ix, 
pp.  228-229;  vol.  x,  p.  148;  vol.  ix,  pp.  188-189;  vol.  i,  pp.  15-16; 
Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Ker  to  Gurley,  New 
Orleans,  April  2,  1832;  East  Attleborough,  December  24,  1831. 


144  THE   AMERICAN    COLONIZATION   SOCIETY 

"When  slaveholders  wrote  for  advice  as  to  the  disposition  of 
their  slaves,  as  they  often  did,  the  Society  consistently  ad- 
vised the  emancipation  of  those  in  bondage,  unless  the  case 
involved  some  peculiar  circumstance.  There  has  been 
found  on  the  records  of  the  Society  no  instance  in  which 
the  organization  ever  assisted  a  slaveholder  to  retain  the 
possession  of  slaves  whose  right  to  liberty  was  called  into 
question.  There  are  a  number  of  instances  in  which  the 
Society  intervened  in  suits  to  secure  the  liberty  of  slaves, 
the  total  number  involved  running  up  into  the  hundreds. 
After  1839  the  organization  became  almost  aggressively 
anti-slavery.  Abandoning  its  former  position — the  use  of 
moral  suasion  to  bring  about  gradual  emancipation — it  be- 
came, in  many  respects,  a  moderate  abolition  society.  Dur- 
ing this  latter  period  it  would  send  throughout  the  land 
reports  on  the  number  of  slaves  offered  to  it,  on  condition 
that  it  would  transport  them,  and  would  directly  appeal 
for  funds  to  secure  the  liberation  of  the  negroes.  It  is  be- 
lieved that  this  is  a  fair  statement  of  its  position  on  the  sub- 
ject of  slavery.  If  so,  it  will  be  seen  that  the  Garrisonians 
did  great  injustice  to  the  whole  movement  and  the  leaders 
engaged  in  it. 

The  fundamental  difference  between  the  Garrisonian  and 
the  Colonizationist  was  this:  the  Garrisonians  approached 
their  task  from  the  point  of  view  of  the  eradication  of  an 
•evil;  the  Colonizationists,  from  the  point  of  view  of  the 
solution  of  a  problem.  Of  the  three  phases  of  the  question, 
the  practicability,  the  desirability,  and  the  method  of  the 
immediate  liberation  of  the  slave,  the  Garrisonian  assumed 
the  first  two  and  considered  only  the  third  a  problem;  the 
•colonizationist  recognized  a  problem  in  all  three.  To  the 
Colonizationist,  the  difference  between  gradual  emancipa- 
tion! and  immediate  emancipation  was  not  equal  to  the 
calamity  of  the  dissolution  of  the  Union,  or  an  American 
•civil  war,  or  both.  To  the  Garrisonian,  the  difference  was 
worth  that  much.  The  Colonizationist  chose  rather  to  de- 
lay the  day  of  complete  emancipation  than  to  live  to  see  the 


457]  COLONIZATION   AND  ABOLITION  145 

day  of  the  division,  probably  a  bloody  division,  of  the 
Union.  The  Garrisonian  chose  the  dissolution  of  the  Union 
rather  than  the  delay  of  a  general  emancipation. 

Whatever  difficulty  present  day  writers  on  the  Abolitionist 
movement  have  in  explaining  the  denial  of  Lincoln  that  he 
was  a  member  of  that  party,  or,  whatever  difficulty  they 
may  have  in  explaining  his  preference  for  Colonization, 
they  may  see,  from  this  point  of  view,  that,  taken  for 
granted  his  paramount  consideration  of  the  Union  and  its 
preservation,  the  only  logical  position  he  could  take  was 
that  taken  by  Colonizationists.  Lincoln  undoubtedly  op- 
posed negro  slavery,  but  the  evidence  seems  conclusive  that 
he  emancipated  the  slaves,  not  out  of  his  hatred  of  slavery, 
but  out  of  his  love  for  the  Union.  He  stated  very  clearly 
his  position  in  the  following  words: 

I  would  save  the  Union.  I  would  save  it  the  shortest  way  under 
the  Constitution.  The  sooner  the  National  authority  can  be  re- 
stored, the  nearer  the  Union  will  be  "the  Union  as  it  was."  If 
there  be  those  who  would  not  save  the  Union  unless  they  could  at 
the  same  time  save  slavery,  I  do  not  agree  with  them.  If  there  be 
those  who  would  not  save  the  Union  unless  they  could  at  the  same 
time  destroy  slavery,  I  do  not  agree  with  them.  My  paramount 
object  in  this  struggle  is  to  save  the  Union  and  is  not  either  to  save 
or  to  destroy  slavery.  If  I  could  save  the  Union  without  freeing  any 
slave,  I  would  do  it ;  and  if  I  could  save  it  by  freeing  all  the  slaves, 
I  would  do  it;  and  if  I  could  save  it  by  freeing  some  and  leaving 
others  alone,  I  would  also  do  that.  What  I  do  about  slavery  and 
the  colored  race,  I  do  because  I  believe  it  helps  to  save  the  Union  ; 
and  what  I  forbear,  I  forbear  because  I  do  not  believe  it  would  help 
to  save  the  Union.88 

The  preservation  of  the  Union  was  his  paramount  consid- 
eration; the  emancipation  of  slaves  was  an  important  con- 
sideration, but  nevertheless,  it  was  a  secondary  considera- 
tion. He  would  have  sacrificed  immediate  emancipation  for 
the  sake  of  preserving  the  Union.  The  Garrisonians  would 
have  sacrificed  the  Union  for  the  sake  of  immediate  eman- 
cipation. In  short,  Lincoln's  position  was  precisely  that  of 
the  Colonizationists  and  precisely  the  opposite  of  that  of  the 
Garrisonians.  If  Garrison's  influence  in  bringing  about  the 

«  J.  F.  Rhodes,  History  of  the  United  States  from  1850-1877,  vol. 
iv,  p.  74. 

10 


146  THE  AMERICAN    COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [458 

Proclamation  of  Emancipation  were  not  overestimated,  and 
if  his  influence  in  bringing  about  the  American  Civil  War 
were  not  underestimated,  he  would  be  given  a  more  just, 
if  not  a  more  exalted,  place  in  American  history. 

A  well  known  historical  writer  assures  us,  in  reference  to 
anti-slavery  leaders,  that  "it  must  not  be  supposed  that 
.  .  .  even  the  agitators  realized  that  slavery  had  the  latent 
power  of  dividing  the  Union  and  bringing  about  civil 
war."58  This  statement,  it  seems,  is  at  variance  with  the 
facts.  Between  1831  and  1845  they  were  so  frequently 
and  so  earnestly  warned  of  the  logical  consequences  of  their 
course,  by  patriots  who  represented  every  section  of  the 
Union,  that  those  who  neglected  those  warnings  must  be 
charged  with  either  ignorance  or  indifference.  If  they  did 
not  see,  it  was  because  they  had  closed  their  eyes  to  the 
light.  When  Harrison  Gray  Otis  of  Boston  spoke  in  Fan- 
euil  Hall,  in  1835,  he  said : 

Now,  sir,  if  it  were  the  object  of  our  meeting  here  to  debate  the 
expediency  of  taking  measures  for  the  abolition  of  slavery,  I  would 
regard  it  as  identical  with  the  question  of  the  expediency  of  dis- 
solving the  Union.  I  am  sure  it  would  be  so  considered  by  the 
Southern  States.  My  conviction  results  from  forty  years  acquaint- 
ance with  prominent  individuals  of  those  States,  of  all  parties,  and 
in  all  the  vicissitudes  of  party.  Be  assured  that  whenever  that  ques- 
tion shall  be  agitated  in  our  public  assemblies,  under  circumstances 
which  should  indicate  the  prevalence  or  the  probability  of  a  general 
sentiment  in  the  free  States  in  favor  of  acting  upon  that  subject, 
the  Union  will  be  at  an  end.  They  would  regard  all  measures  ema- 
nating from  such  a  sentiment  as  war  in  disguise  upon  their  lives, 
their  property,  their  rights  and  institutions,  an  outrage  upon  their 
pride  and  honor,  and  the  faith  of  contracts — menacing  the  purity  of 
their  women,  the  safety  of  their  children,  the  comfort  of  their  homes 
and  their  hearths,  and,  in  a  word,  all  that  a  man  holds  dear.  In 
these  opinions  they  might  be  mistaken,  but  in  support  of  them  they 
would  exhibit  a  spectacle  of  unanimity  unparallelled  among  so  nu- 
merous a  population  upon  any  subject,  at  any  time,  in  any  part  of 
the  world.69 

"  Every  effort,"1  said  he,  "  intended  to  propagate  a  general 
sentiment  favorable  to  the  immediate  abolition  of  slavery, 
is  of  forbidding  aspect  and  ruinous  tendency."  "  I  wit- 
nessed the  adoption  of  the  Constitution,  and  through  a  long 

68  Hart,  Slavery  and  Abolition,  p.  3. 
"African  Repository,  vol.  xi,  pp.  311-318. 


459]  COLONIZATION   AND  ABOLITION  147 

series  of  years,  have  been  accustomed  to  rely  upon  an  adher- 
ence to  it  as  the  foundation  of  all  my  hopes  for  posterity. 
It  is  threatened,  I  think,  with  the  most  portentous  danger 
that  has  yet  arisen." 

Judge  William  Halsey  of  New  Jersey  expressed  his  view 
of  the  results  of  abolitionism : 

It  is  time  for  the  friends  of  Colonization  to  come  out  and  .  .  . 
shew  the  extremely  dangerous  tendency  of  their  proceedings  and 
oppose  by  every  means  except  force,  mobs,  and  lynch  laws.  The 
situation  of  things  requires  the  serious  consideration  of  the  friends 
of  the  harmony  and  integrity  of  the  Union.  We  appear  to  be  asleep 
upon  a  volcano,  insensible  of  our  danger.  It  may  soon  burst  forth 
and  spread  desolation  throughout  our  land.60 

The  general  agent  of  the  Colonization  Society  for  Massa- 
chusetts wrote  of  the  doctrines  of  the  ultra- Abolitionists : 

It  was  seen  by  some  from  the  beginning  that  the  leaders  of  that 
society  were  propagating  a  deep  and  refined  metaphysical  system, 
which  must  naturally  end  in  the  "no-human-government  theory"; 
in  the  doctrine  that  not  only  slavery,  but  the  state,  the  church,  and 
even  the  legal  relations  of  husbands  and  wives,  parents  and  children, 
ought  to  be  abolished.61 

In  a  debate  in  the  Senate  in  1839  Henry  Clay  declared 
that  the  ultra-Abolitionists  were  resolved  to  persevere  at  all 
hazards  and  without  regard  to  consequences,  however  ca- 
lamitous. Continuing,  he  said: 

With  them,  the  rights  of  property  are  nothing;  the  deficiency  of 
the  powers  of  the  General  Government  is  nothing;  the  acknowledged 
and  incontestible  powers  of  the  States  are  nothing;  civil  war,  a  dis- 
solution of  the  Union,  and  the  overthrow  of  a  government  in  which 
are  concentrated  the  fondest  hopes  of  the  civilized  world,  are  noth- 
ing. A  single  idea  has  taken  possession  of  their  minds,  and  onward 
they  pursue  it,  overlooking  all  barriers,  reckless  and  regardless  of 
all  consequences.  .  .  .  Utterly  destitute  of  constitutional  or  other 
rightful  power,  living  in  totally  distinct  communities  as  alien  to  the 
communities  in  which  the  subject  on  which  they  would  operate  re- 
sides, so  far  as  concerns  political  power  over  that  subject,  as  if  they 
lived  in  Africa  or  Asia,  they  nevertheless  promulgate  to  the  world 
their  purpose  to  be  to  manumit  forthwith,  .  .  .  and  without  moral 
preparation,  three  millions  of  negro  slaves,  under  jurisdictions  alto- 
gether separated  from  those  under  which  they  live.  .  .  .  Does  any 
considerate  man  believe  it  to  be  possible  to  effect  such  an  object 
without  convulsion,  revolution,  and  bloodshed?  .  .  .  The  abolition- 
ists, let  me  suppose,  succeed  in  their  present  aim  of  uniting  the 

60  Letters   of   American    Colonization    Society,    MS.,   Halsey  to 
Wilkeson,  Newark,  January  12,  1841. 
"African  Repository,  vol.  xviii,  pp.  369-376. 


148  THE  AMERICAN   COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [460 

inhabitants  of  the  free  States  as  one  man,  against  the  inhabitants 
of  the  slave  States.  Union  on  the  one  side  will  beget  union  on  the 
other.  And  this  process  of  reciprocal  consolidation  will  be  attended 
with  all  the  violent  prejudices,  embittered  passions,  and  implacable 
animosities  which  ever  degraded  or  deformed  human  nature.  A 
virtual  dissolution  of  the  Union  will  have  taken  place,  whilst  the 
forms  of  its  existence  remain.  .  .  .  One  section  will  stand  in  men- 
acing and  hostile  array  against  the  other.  The  collision  of  opinion 
will  be  quickly  followed  by  a  clash  of  arms.  I  will  not  attempt  to 
describe  scenes  which  now  happily  lie  concealed  from  our  view.62 

In  Ohio,  Elisha  Whittksey  in  1839  openly  charged  the 
Abolitionists  with  views  hostile  to  the  Union,  "  as  well  from 
the  tendency  of  their  measures,  as  from  a  sermon  preached 
last  year  at  Braintree,  Massachusetts,  that  went  the  rounds, 
as  canonical;  in  which  a  separation  of  the  Union  is  hailed 
as  the  most  happy  of  all  events."63  In  1833  C.  F.  Mercer, 
of  Virginia,  gave  this  challenge  to  the  Abolitionists : 

Let  those  who  oppose  the  colonization  of  Africa,  by  our  colored 
population,  because  it  is  not  a  scheme  for  the  immediate  abolition 
of  slavery  in  America,  justify,  if  they  can,  to  God  and  man,  their 
hostility  to  a  plan  of  enlarged  policy,  as  well  as  of  expanded  be- 
nevolence and  piety,  because  it  does  not  propose  to  accomplish  all 
that  they  desire,  and  because  they  desire  to  do  that  which  if  accom- 
plished, as  they  propose,  would  prostrate  the  fair  fabric  of  our 
Union,  and  with  it  the  hopes  of  freedom  to  man.6* 

James  Garland,  of  Virginia,  said  of  the  effects  of  Garri- 
sonian  abolitionism :  "  Week  by  week,  day  by  day,  and  hour 
by  hour,  they  are  creating  among  your  youth  feelings  of 
strong  prejudice  and  hostility  to  the  institutions  of  the 
South,"  and  he  stated  in  unmistakable  terms  that  aggressive 
action  from  the  North  would  be  met  with  a  definite,  united 
opposition  from  the  South.65  John  Tyler  in  1838  said: 
"Philanthropy,  when  separated  from  policy,  is  the  most 
dangerous  agent  in  human  affairs.  It  is  no  way  distin- 
guishable from  fanaticism."  Of  that  form  of  philanthropy 
called  abolition,  he  says :  "  It  would  pull  down  the  pillars  of 
the  constitution,  and  even  now  shakes  them  most  terri- 
bly. .  .  ,"68 

62  Ibid.,  vol.  xv,  p.  50  ff. 

63  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Whittlesey  to 
Wilkeson,  Canfield,  Ohio,  November  27,  1839. 

64  African  Repository,  vol.  ix,  pp.  265-267. 
86  Ibid.,  vol.  xiv,  pp.  43-47. 

68  27th  Cong.,  3d  sess.,  H.  Rept.  No.  283,  p.  961. 


461]  COLONIZATION   AND  ABOLITION  149 

The  secretary  of  the  Colonization  Society  saw  clearly  the 
tendency  of  Garrisonian  Abolition,  and  he  deplored  the  rash- 
ness which  prompted  it.  Nowhere  is  the  real  unionist  spirit 
of  the  Society  better  set  forth  than  in  his  letters  written  to 
its  Managers.  He  traveled  and  knew  sentiment  in  every 
part  of  the  Union ;  and  he  writes  from  New  York,  in  1834 : 

For  one,  I  feel  that  an  awful  crisis  is  fast  coming  upon  the  coun- 
try and  that  the  slave  question  is  to  shake  the  Union.  ...  If  the 
mild  principles  of  our  Society  can  [  ?]  in  the  public  mind,  all  will  be 
safe.  But  if  the  pulpit  and  press  of  the  North  is  to  be  enlisted  in 
the  cause  of  instant  unconditional  Abolition,  the  whole  land  will  be 
filled  with  violence.  The  signs  of  the  times  are  portentous.67 

The  next  summer  he  wrote  from  Boston : 

That  the  centre  of  the  nation  is  to  be  deeply  moved  and  speedily 
on  the  subject  of  slavery  is  certain.  At  the  next  Congress,  we 
should,  .  .  .  make  a  powerful  and  earnest  appeal  to  the  General 
Government.  Nothing  can  be  lost  by  such  a  measure — everything 
may  be  gained — the  preservation  of  the  Union,  a  gradual,  cautious, 
plan  of  voluntary  emancipation,  and  the  regeneration  of  Africa. 
Should  the  doctrines  and  measures  of  the  Abolitionists  predominate 
in  the  non-slaveholding  States,  disunion,  if  not  a  general  servile  war 
will  follow.68 

The  plain  unvarnished  fact  is  that  William  Lloyd  Garri- 
son was  woefully  deficient  in  his  love  for  the  American 
Union.  To  produce  conclusive  evidence  of  this,  it  is  only 
necessary  to  quote  three  resolutions  offered  by  him  at  a 
meeting  of  the  Essex  (Massachusetts)  Anti-Slavery  So- 
ciety, in  1842 : 

Resolved,  That  the  American  Union  is  and  ever  has  been  since 
the  adoption  of  the  Constitution,  a  rope  of  sand — a  fanciful  non- 
entity— a  mere  piece  of  parchment — "a  rhetorical  flourish  and  splen- 
did absurdity" — and  a  concentration  of  the  physical  force  of  the 
nation  to  destroy  liberty,  and  uphold  slavery. 

Resolved,  That  the  safety,  prosperity,  and  perpetuity  of  the  non- 
slaveholding  States  require  that  their  connection  be  immediately 
dissolved  with  the  slavehplding  States  in  form,  as  it  is  now  in  fact 

Resolved,  That  the  petition  presented  to  the  U.  S.  House  of  Rep- 
resentatives, by  John  Q.  Adams,  from  sundry  inhabitants  of  Haver- 
hill,  in  this  county,  praying  Congress  to  take  measures  for  a  peace- 
ful dissolution  of  the  Union,  meets  our  deliberate  and  cordial 
approval.69 

67  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Gurley  to  Gales, 
New  York,  April  17,  1834. 

68  Ibid.,  Gurley  to  Fendall,  Boston,  August  3,  1835;  Gurley  to 
Gales,  Portland,  September  18,  1835. 

69  African  Repository,  June,  1842,  vol.  xviii,  p.  189. 


I5O  THE   AMERICAN    COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [462 

If  the  antislavery  agitators  did  not  realize  "that  slavery 
had  the  latent  power  of  dividing  the  Union  and  bringing 
about  civil  war,"  it  was  not  for  lack  of  warning  from  the 
sanest  statesmen  of  the  time. 

If  the  spirit  of  Garrisonianism  was  the  spirit  of  disunion, 
the  spirit  of  Colonization  was  the  spirit  of  national  unity.70 
Garrison's  attempt  to  "prick  the  consciences"  of  slave- 
holders ended  by  hardening,  rather  than  "  pricking "  them, 
and  the  result  was  sectional  bitterness.  Garrison  broke  the 
bonds  of  Union;  Colonizationists  attempted  to  heal  them. 
The  tendency  of  Abolition  was  to  pull  to  pieces ;  the  tend- 
ency of  Colonization  was  to  bind  together.  The  Garri- 
sonians  believed  in  antagonism ;  the  Colonizationists  believed 
in  cooperation.  The  Abolitionist  slandered;  the  Coloniza- 
tionist  sympathized.  When  the  slaveholder  passed  by,  the 
Abolitionist  pointed  the  finger  of  scorn  at  him ;  the  Coloni- 
zationist  called  him  brother,  and  sought  to  help  him  solve 
his  problem — the  negro  problem.  The  Abolitionist  ex- 
claimed, "You  must";  the  Colonizationist  said,  "Let's  see 
if  we  can."  The  most  important  unofficial  organization  in 
making  the  Civil  War  irrepressible,  if  it  was  irrepressible, 
was  ultra- Abolitionism ;  the  most  important  unofficial  or- 
ganization in  trying  to  bring  about  a  peaceable  settlement  of 
the  negro  problem  was  the  Colonization  Society. 

It  must  not  be  forgotten  that  Garrisonians  were  attempt- 
ing— or,  what  was  the  same,  so  far  as  the  alienation  of  the 
South  was  concerned,  forced  the  South  to  the  belief  that 
they  were  attempting — to  do  a  thing  that  was  in  plain  viola- 
tion of  the  federal  Constitution.  The  most  eminent  consti- 
tutional lawyers  in  the  United  States  agreed  that  the  federal 
government  had  no  power  to  interfere  with  the  institution 
of  slavery  in  those  States  in  which  it  existed.  Daniel 
Webster's  view  was  as  follows : 

70  Ibid.,  vol.  i,  p.  225;  Nov.,  1832,  p.  275;  Minutes  of  Boarr'.  of 
Managers  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  November  20, 
1835,  p.  197;  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Wilke- 
son  to  Rev.  A.  Yates,  March  31,  1840,  No.  141. 


463]  COLONIZATION   AND   ABOLITION  1$! 

In  my  opinion,  the  domestic  slavery  of  the  Southern  States  is  a 
subject  within  the  exclusive  control  of  the  States  themselves;  and 
this,  I  am  sure,  is  the  opinion  of  the  whole  North.  Congress  has 
no  right  to  interfere  in  the  emancipation  of  slaves,  or  in  the  treat- 
ment of  them  in  any  of  the  States.71 

We  have  already  seen  that  Clay's  views  coincided  with 
that  of  Webster.  Harrison  Gray  Otis  was  convinced  that 
the  Garrisonians  were  attempting  to  ignore  the  limitations 
of  that  instrument.72  Even  the  constitution  of  the  Ameri- 
can Anti-Slavery  Society  contained  the  admission  "that 
each  State  in  which  slavery  exists  has  by  the  Constitution 
of  the  United  States  the  exclusive  right  to  legislate  in  regard 
to  its  abolition  in  said  State."73  And  when  it  was  proposed 
in  the  New  York  Anti-Slavery  Convention  in  1838  to  elimi- 
nate a  clause  of  its  constitution  similar  to  that  just  quoted, 
both  Judge  William  Jay  and  Wendall  Phillips  opposed  the 
elimination.  Jay  asked:  "Is  there  a  sane  person  in  this 
assembly,  who  does  not  in  his  heart  believe  that  ...  a  law 
[a  general  abolition  law]  passed  by  Congress,  instead  of 
breaking  the  fetters  of  the  slave,  would  instantly  dissolve 
the  bands  of  this  Union  ?  The  South  would  not  and  ought 
not  to  submit  to  a  usurpation  so  flagrant  and  profligate."7* 
And  yet,  it  was  just  such  attempts  as  this  that  led  Southern- 
ers to  distrust  the  movements  of  their  opponents. 

To  Colonizationists  it  seemed  worse  than  useless,  it 
seemed  the  height  of  folly,  to  make  constant  and  consistent 
use  of  slander  and  abuse  in  the  attempt  to  bring  about 
emancipation  in  the  South,  which  could  constitutionally  be 
brought  about  only  with  the  consent  and  by  the  action  of  the 
slave  States  themselves.  The  Colonizationists  were  right. 
The  difference  between  the  policy  pursued  by  the  Abolition- 
ists and  that  pursued  by  the  Colonizationists  was  the  differ- 
ence between  the  inevitableness  of  a  civil  war,  before  a 
general  emancipation,  and  the  improbability  of  such  a  war, 
before  a  general  emancipation. 

71  African  Repository,  vol.  ix,  pp.  188-189. 

!Ibid.,  vol.  xi,  pp.  311-318. 
78  Ibid.,  vol.  xiv,  p.  173. 
74  Ibid.,  vol.  xiv,  p.  182  ff. 


152  THE  AMERICAN    COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [464 

The  essential  mistake  the  Garrisonians  made  was  in  as- 
suming that  every  slaveholder  was  a  slaveholder  from 
choice,  and  therefore,  might  be  justly  called  a  "  manstealer," 
"  liar,"  etc.  ad  infinitum.  For  instance,  the  Garrisonian 
denunciation  was  applicable  to  Mrs.  Dabney  Minor,  of  Vir- 
ginia, who  bought  two  negro  slaves  for  the  express  purpose 
of  freeing  them  and  sending  them  to  Liberia.75  Mrs.  Mary 
B.  Blackford,  also  of  Virginia,  in  her  private  letters  to  the 
Society  frequently  lamented  the  existence  of  the  institution 
in  her  State.  "From  childhood  I  have  bewailed  the  unnum- 
bered ills  of  slavery.  This  (the  Colonization  Society)  is 
the  only  plan  at  all  practicable,  of  lessening,  or  removing 
them,  and  fervent  is  the  love  and  gratitude  I  feel,  to  those 
who  like  you  do  much  for  this  great  cause."76  She  was 
pained  to  read  in  the  Garrisonian  periodicals  wholesale 
denunciation,  for  she  knew  that  many  persons  at  the  South 
"make  the  most  noble  sacrifices  for  the  benefit  of  the 
negro."17 

The  Liberator's  blanket  invective  was  applicable  also  to 
Mrs.  Ann  R.  Page,  of  Virginia — than  whom  not  a  purer  or 
a  nobler  spirit  lived  in  the  whole  of  New  England — and  yet, 
a  slaveholder!  This  combination  was  incomprehensible  to 
the  Garrisonian.  Ergo,  Mrs.  Page  was  a  "hypocrite,"  a 
"  manstealer/'  a  "  liar," — in  short,  was  doomed  to  everlast- 
ing punishment.  And  yet,  Mrs.  Page  almost  wore  her  life 
away  in  anxiety  over  the  welfare  of  her  negroes.  Day 
after  day,  for  years,  she  gathered  them  together  each  morn- 
ing and  prayers  were  offered,  scripture  read,  and  they  were 
urged  to  lead  such  lives  as  their  mistress  hoped  for  them. 
The  expense  involved  in  keeping  them  as  she  thought  they 
should  be  kept  brought  on  the  estate  a  large  debt.  In  the 
midst  of  her  perplexities  her  husband  died  and,  by  the  laws 

75  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  W.  S.  White 
to  Gurley,  Charlottesville,  Va.,  April  7,  1839. 

76  Ibid.,  M.  B.  Blackford  to  Gurley,  Fredericksburg,  Va.,  Septem- 
ber 18,  1840. 

77  Ibid.,   M.   B.   Blackford,   Fredericksburg,   Va.,   September   18, 
1840. 


465]  COLONIZATION  AND  ABOLITION  153 

of  the  State,  the  slaves  had  to  be  sold — one  of  the  greatest 
trials  of  her  life  was  to  see  the  law  take  its  course  in  this 
instance.  Of  her  slaves  she  said : 

My  purpose  respecting  these  people  I  hold  to  be  so  sacred  that  I 
desire  not,  and  even  fear  to  counsel  with  my  dearest  and  wisest 
friends,  because  they  would  all  advise  me  to  relieve  myself  from 
this  bondage  in  which  I  outwardly  live,  and  which,  in  their  kind- 
ness for  me,  they  have  thought  would  ere  now  have  ended  my  days. 
...  I  come  to  Thee,  and  look  up  through  the  blood  of  the  Cove- 
nant for  direction  in  all  the  affairs  of  this  estate.  And  with  regard 
to  the  frequent  failures  of  some  of  these  people  in  duty,  let  me  not 
be  put  off  by  these  things,  from  my  settled  purpose  of  doing  them 
good. 

When  the  day  for  the  forced  sale  came,  she  retired  to  her 
room,  dreading  the  probability  that  a  number  of  the  slaves 
would  be  purchased  by  the  slavedealers  present  and  sent  to 
the  States  at  the  Southwest.  Against  this  she  prayed ;  and 
when  the  sale  was  over,  it  was  found  that  although  more 
than  one  hundred  had  been  sold  (many, still  remained  un- 
sold) not  one  had  fallen  into  those  dreaded  hands.  The 
negroes  were  all  to  remain  near  their  former  home.  If  this 
were  the  place,  it  would  be  a  pleasant  task  to  go  further 
into  the  story  of  the  life  of  this  exalted  character,  whose 
treatment  of  her  "people"  was  known  throughout  the  en- 
tire State,  and  whose  life  would  have  been  a  benediction  to 
any  community  in  which  she  lived — even  a  community  com- 
posed entirely  of  Garrisonians  !78 

Taken  baldly,  as  stated  by  Garrison,  his  unmeasured 
words  were  applicable  also  to  General  John  H.  Cocke,  of 
Bremo,  Virginia,  whose  hesitation  about  sending  his  ne- 
groes, those  who  were  willing  to  go,  to  Liberia  arose,  not 
from  his  unwillingness  to  be  rid  of  slaves  but  from  his  con- 
viction that  they  were  not  able  to  care  for  themselves.  At 
last  he  found  among  them  a  valuable  man,  a  stone  mason, 
a  man  of  good  moral  character  and  who  gave  promise  of 
doing  well  for  his  family  and  for  the  colony.  For  six 
months  before  the  slave  expressed  his  willingness  to  leave 
Bremo,  his  liberty  had  been  at  his  option.  With  him  were 

"Ibid.,  Mrs.  A.  R.  Page  to  Gurley,  Milwood,  Va.,  March  26, 
1831 ;  African  Repository,  vol.  xx,  pp.  298-305. 


154  THE  AMERICAN   COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [466 

to  go  his  wife  and  six  children.79  While  the  head  of  the 
house  was  interested  in  the  colonization  of  his  blacks,  the 
mistress,  no  matter  how  many  visitors  had  come  to  enjoy 
her  hospitality,  every  day  gathered  the  children  of  her 
"  people  "  for  instruction,  while  a  pastor  was  employed  to 
give  religious  instruction  to  their  parents.80  Finally,  the 
all-inclusive  character  of  Garrison's  criticism  covered  the 
case  of  Miss  Mary  C.  Moore,  of  North  Carolina,  who  was 
not  only  willing  but  anxious  to  liberate  her  eight  or  ten 
negroes  and  pay  the  expense  of  their  transportation  to  Li- 
beria, although  her  needle  was  her  only  means  of  support 
when  the  slaves  were  gone.  A  citizen  of  her  community, 
who  was  unwilling  to  see  her  bear  this  expense,  asked  a 
pointed  and  significant  question:  "Do  you  know  of  any 
abolitionist  who  will  take  these  slaves  and  send  them  to  Li- 
beria, or  place  them  in  a  state  of  freedom,  in  any  of  the 
States  in  which  it  is  permitted  to  emancipate,  or  in  which 
free  colored  persons  may  reside?  Miss  M.  will  cheerfully 
yield  her  right  to  such  individuals.  But  she  prefers  Africa."81 
In  so  far  as  the  Abolitionists  opposed  the  system  of  slav- 
ery, there  can  be  no  doubt  that  they  did  a  great  service  to 
the  cause  of  human  freedom ;  but  when  this  opposition  took, 
as  it  continually  did  among  the  Garrisonians,  the  form  of 
intemperate  and  untrue  pictures  of  the  system,  and  when 
it  was  distinctly  applied  in  terms  of  personal  abuse  and 
slander  to  every  man  or  woman  in  the  South  who  owned  a 
single  slave,  it  tended  more  and  more  not  only  to  make  a 
general  and  peaceable  emancipation  an  utter  impossibility, 
but  also  to  result  in  the  enactment  of  measures  more  strin- 
gent than  ever  by  State  legislatures  against  the  privilege  of 
emancipating;  and  it  was  probably  the  means  of  preventing 
many  a  negro  from  securing  his  emancipation  at  the  hands 

79  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Cooke  to  Gur- 
ley,  Bremo,  March  31,  1833. 

80  Ibid.,  S.  B.  S.  Bissel  to  McLain,  Greenwich,  Conn.,  February 
IS,  1845- 

81  Ibid.,  T.  P.  Hunt  to  Gurley,  Wilmington,  N.  C.,  June  17,  1834; 
African  Repository,  vol.  xvi,  pp.  263-264. 


467]  COLONIZATION    AND   ABOLITION  I  $5 

of  his  owner.  It  thus  resulted  in  precisely  that  which  the 
Garrisonians  professed  to  oppose :  "  If  it  were  evident  that 
only  by  a  short  delay,  he  could  be  better  prepared  to  receive 
the  boon  of  liberty,  still  the  slave  ought  to  be  a  free  man 
now."82 

It  must  not  be  supposed  that  the  writer  is  unmindful  of 
the  fact  that,  during  that  important  decade  beginning  with 
1830,  there  was  going  on  in  the  lower  South  a  most  impor- 
tant change  of  sentiment  on  the  whole  question  of  slavery, 
and  that  this  change  must  not  be  too  largely  attributed  to 
resentment  that  resulted  from  Garrison's  methods.  That 
change  of  sentiment  was  due,  in  great  measure,  to  the  rapid 
development  of  the  Southwest  and  the  increase  in  cotton 
production.  Laborers  were  needed;  the  soil  was,  much  of 
it,  virgin  and  fertile;  negro  labor  seemed  admirably  suited 
to  the  cultivation  of  cotton.  The  economic  wastefulness  of 
the  slave  system  was  not  yet  duly  appreciated.  The  result 
was  the  internal  slave  trade  between  the  upper  and  the  lower 
South.  Professor  Thomas  Dew's  contribution  to  the  Pro- 
Slavery  Argument  is  indicative  of  this  profound  revolution 
in  the  attitude  of  the  South  toward  both  negro  slavery  and 
the  Colonization  Society.  The  Society  made  an  effort  to 
counteract  the  influence  that  Professor  Dew's  essay  was 
undoubtedly  beginning  to  have. 

Jesse  Burton  Harrison  wrote  his  Review  of  the  Slave 
Question  after  correspondence  with  and  with  the  coopera- 
tion of  the  most  important  officials  of  the  Colonization  So- 
ciety,, who  gave  him  every  encouragement.  Harrison  states 
the  burden  of  his  essay  to  be  as  follows : 

To  show  the  necessity  of  her  [Virginia,  in  particular,  and  the  South, 
in  general]  promptly  doing  something  to  check  the  palpable  mis- 
chiefs her  prosperity  is  suffering  from  slavery.  We  design  to  show 
that  all  her  sources  ^of  economical  prosperity  are  poisoned  by  slav- 
ery, and  we  shall  hint  at  its  moral  evils  only  as  they  occasion  or 
imply  destruction  to  the  real  prosperity  of  a  nation.83 

He  undertook  to  show  that  "  an  improving  system  of  agri- 

82  See  above.     . 

88  J.  B.  Harrison,  Review  of  the  Slave  Question,  pp.  9-15. 


156  THE   AMERICAN    COLONIZATION    SOCIETY  [468 

culture  cannot  be  carried  on  by  slaves  " ;  that  no  soil,  except 
the  richest  can  be  profitably  cultivated  by  slaves,  and  even 
then  only  if  its  fertility  is  inexhaustible;  that  slaves  are  unfit 
to  develop  manufactures,  one  of  the  needs  of  the  South; 
that  "slave  labour  is,  without  controversy,  dearer  than 
free  " ;  and  that  slavery  discourages  immigration.  He  further 
declared  that  "  Virginia  possesses  scarcely  a  single  requisite 
to  make  a  prosperous  slave  labour  State."  "We  state  as 
the  result  of  extensive  inquiry,  embracing  the  last  fifteen 
years,  that  a  very  great  proportion  of  the  larger  plantations, 
with  from  fifty  to  one  hundred  slaves,  actually  bring  their 
proprietors  in  debt  at  the  end  of  a  short  term  of  years.  .  .  ." 
Undoubtedly  Dew's  Essay  had  far  more  influence  than 
did  that  of  Harrison.  The  effort,  in  this  study,  is  not  to 
minimize  the  importance  of  the  change  that  came  over  the 
South  as  a  result  of  economic  conditions,  or  to  exaggerate 
the  influence  of  the  Garrisonians,  but  rather  to  compare  the 
methods  used  by  Colonizationists  and  Garrisonians  and  to 
set  forth  that,  while  both  were  positively  opposed  to  the 
slave  system,  the  methods  of  the  latter  were  pregnant  with 
serious  mischief,  while  those  of  the  former  were  indicative 
of  a  farsighted  statesmanship.  Dr.  S.  M.  E.  Goheen,  the 
Missionary  of  the  Methodist  Episcopal  Church  to  Liberia, 
said  in  1838: 

Having  been  educated  in  a  non-slaveholding  State,  I  was  daily 
taught  to  look  upon  the  man  who  held  slaves  as  a  monster  scarcely 
human,  and  at  all  times  to  regard  those  engaged  in  or  holding  slaves 
as  participating  in  crimes  of  the  deepest  dye;  and  notwithstanding 
I  have  resided  in  one,  and  traveled  in  several  slave  States,  and  never 
beheld  the  shade  of  a  shadow  o"  an  attempt  at  the  cruelties  said  to 
be  practiced  (daily)  upon  the  slaves,  yet  it  was  impossible  for  me 
to  overcome  early  prejudices,  or  to  believe  anything  else  than  that 
slavery  as  there  practiced,  was  the  greatest  evil  in  the  States,  or  in 
the  world,  which  I  now  very  much  doubt.8* 

Instead  of  the  methods  used  by  the  Garrisonians,  the  em- 
ployment of  statements  untrue,  in  point  of  fact,  and  foolish, 
in  point  of  policy,  the  Colonizationists  came  much  nearer 
the  true  statement  of  conditions  in  the  slaveholding  States 

8*  African  Repository,  vol.  xiv,  pp.  364-365. 


COLONIZATION   AND   ABOLITION 

and  nearer  securing  the  cooperation  of  the  South  in  a  grad- 
ual emancipation,  by  the  employment  of  more  accurate 
statements.  This  is  well  exemplified  in  a  letter  written  by 
Gurley  while  in  England  in  1841 : 

I  will  not  question  the  Honesty  and  benevolence  of  the  great  body 
of  English  and  American  Abolitionists,  yet  I  regard  many  of  their 
writings  and  proceedings  as  unjust  to  the  public  of  the  United 
States,  particularly  to  the  slaveholders  and  pernicious  in  all  their 
tendencies.  No  one  can  more  desire  than  the  writer  to  see  modi- 
fication and  amendment  of  the  legal  codes  of  the  slaveholding 
States,  in  favor  of  the  slaves.  Atrocious  crimes  and  cruelties  are 
doubtless  occasionally  committed,  in  those  States,  on  the  persons  of 
slaves.  .  .  .  Generally  (and  I  speak  from  personal  observation  and 
inquiry  in  nearly  all  the  Southern  States  of  the  American  republic,) 
the  citizens  of  those  States  are  kind,  humane,  generous,  and,  in  pro- 
portion to  the  whole  population,  equal  to  that  found  in  most  parts 
of  Christendom,  devout  and  exemplary  Christians.  No  better  friends 
have  the  slaves  in  any  part  of  the  world  than  are  to  be  found  in 
those  States.  Cases  of  harsh  treatment,  of  severe  punishment,  of 
wanton  disregard  of  their  feelings,  of  the  voluntary  and  cruel  rup- 
ture of  their  domestic  ties,  of  withholding  ,  .  .  the  necessaries  of 
life,  or  denying  to  them  opportunities  to  hear  Christian  instruction 
and  worship  God,  are  not  common ;  they  are  exceptions,  not  the  rule. 
Liabilities  to  evil  in  the  system  of  slavery  are  great;  trying  separa- 
tions and  wrongs  among  the  slaves  frequent,  yet  many  laws  which 
darken  the  statute  books  of  the  slaveholding  States  are  in  practice 
nearly,  if  not  quite,  obsolete;  and  humanity  and  religion  are  exert- 
ing a  mighty  and  increasing  influence  for  the  protection  and  good 
of  this  dependent  people. 

Many,  very  many,  masters  and  slaves  are  bound  together  by  the 
ties  of  mutual  confidence  and  affection.  A  large  proportion  of  the 
slaves  exhibit  an  aspect  of  comfort,  contentment,  and  cheerfulness. 
There  is  much  to  regret,  much  to  condemn,  fearful  evils  which  are 
perhaps  never  brought  to  light,  in  the  system  of  slavery;  yet  all 
things  (the  very  heavens  themselves,  as  some  would  represent)  are 
not  wrapt  in  gloom.  It  is  not  to  diminish  the  general  sense  of 
injustice  as  well  as  impolicy  of  slavery,  viewed  as  a  permanent 
system,  that  I  thus  write,  nor  that  I  would  lessen  the  moral  powers 
that  are  working  for  its  abolition,  but  in  reference  to  truth,  and 
because  he  is  blind  who  sees  not  that  injustice  to  the  master  is 
injury  and  a  crime  against  the  slave.  He  who  bears  false  witness 
against  me,  and  seeks  to  destroy  my  reputation,  must  not  expect  to 
be  my  counsellor.  If  the  abolitionists  of  New  England  and  Old 
England  have  no  influence  among  American  slaveholders,  and  little 
with  the  citizens  generally  of  the  United  States,  to  their  errors  in 
principle,  and  more  to  their  faults  and  offences  in  practice,  must 
they  trace  the  cause.85 

Let  us  compare  the  effects  on  public  opinion  of  these  two 
methods,  the  Abolition  method  of  antagonism  and  abuse  and 

*s  27th  Cong.,  3d  sess.,  H.  Rept.  No.  283,  pp.  1024-1025. 


158  THE  AMERICAN    COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [4/0 

the  Colonization  method  of  cooperation  and  sympathy,  the 
one  designed  to  bring  about  the  immediate,  and  the  other 
the  gradual  abolition  of  slavery. 

Dr.  John  Ker,  one  of  the  most  prominent  Colonizationists 
in  the  South,  who  almost  single-handed  succeeded  in  defend- 
ing the  right  of  individuals  of  Louisiana  to  emancipate  their 
slaves  when  they  were  willing  to  send  them  to  the  colony, 
when  the  State  legislature  was  about  to  enact  a  very  radical 
measure  denying  that  right  to  a  slaveholder  who  offered 
upwards  of  three  hundred  slaves  to  the  Society,86  wrote, 
in  1831 : 

The  greatest  difficulty  we  have  to  encounter  is  the  jealousy  of 
Northern  interference,  and  of  what  the  world  thinks  proper  to  call, 
"religious  fanaticism."  What,  with  you  and  me  and  all  Christians 
would  constitute  the  highest  motive  to  exertion  in  this  course, 
would  only  tend  in  Louisiana,  (if  urged  at  all),  to  paralyze  and 
destroy  the  force  of  other  motives,  which  fortunately  are  sufficient. 
I  have  myself  received  permission  to  use  the  names  of  some  of  the 
most  influential  men  in  the  State ;  but  it  is  difficult  for  you  to  con- 
ceive how  essential  it  will  be  to  present  and  great  success,  to  avoid 
most  scrupulously,  anything  which  could  excite  the  morbid  sensi- 
bility of  slaveholders  and  Southern  men  by  jealousy  of  our  North- 
ern Brethren.87 

Let  those  who  still  believe  that  there  existed  between  the 
Colonization  Society  and  the  slaveholders  of  Virginia  a  col- 
lusion whose  object  was  the  perpetuation  of  slavery,  read 
the  following  comment  upon  the  result  of  Garrisonian 
methods.  A  careful  perusal  of  the  quoted  extracts  from 
this  private  letter  of  a  prominent  Virginian  ought  to  carry 
some  weight  in  our  views  relative  to  ( i )  the  supposed  tend- 
ency of  the  Society  to  "rivet  the  chains  of  the  slaves,"  (2) 
the  views  of  active  Southern  Colonizationists  on  the  subject 
of  emancipation,  (3)  the  methods  advised  by  these  men  to 
bring  about  emancipation,  (4)  characteristics  of  the  South- 
ern temper  on  the  whole  subject  of  slavery,  (5)  the  effects 
of  Garrisonian  abuse.  The  writer  says : 

It  is  a  great  mistake  to  suppose  that  the  people  of  our  State  gen- 
erally will  shrink  from  .  .  .  discussion,  or  are  too  sensitive  to  per- 

86  African  Repository,  vol.  xviii,  p.  99  ff. 

87  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Ker  to  Gur- 
ley,  Natchez,  Miss.,  November  24,  1831. 


COLONIZATION  AND  ABOLITION  159 

mit  it.  On  the  contrary,  I  believe  a  very  large  proportion  of  the 
people,  are  willing  to  enquire  into  the  merits  of  the  slave  system, 
and  that  many  have  their  minds  open  to  conviction  upon  the  sub- 
ject. Such  violent  tirades,  however,  as  those  issuing  from  the 
Anti-slavery  presses  of  the  North  are  calculated  to  do  infinite  mis- 
chief to  the  cause,  and  to  rivet  with  a  double  bolt,  the  bonds  they 
are  intended  to  lose.  You  know  that  no  man  is  more  opposed  to 
slavery  than  I  am  and  have  been  for  years.  It  is  not,  therefore, 
that  any  of  their  declamations  about  cruelty,  manstealing,  etc.,  has 
any  effect  on  me,  that  I  deplore  their  course,  but  I  confess  I  am 
vexed  to  think  that  we,  who  entertain  opinions  averse  to  slavery 
here,  who  are  ready  and  willing  upon  all  proper  occasions  to  assert 
and  act  upon  them,  who  are  perfectly  acquainted  with  the  subject, 
and  with  the  temper  of  the  people  in  this  matter,  should  see  all  our 
hopes  of  finally  eradicating  this  evil,  spoiled  and  marred  by  the 
intemperance  and  folly,  not  to  say  wickedness,  of  those  who  are 
perfectly  ignorant  of  the  subject,  its  difficulties  and  dangers,  but  who 
ruin  our  chance  of  influence,  by  professing  a  common  object  with 
us.  The  object  of  all  discussion  on  this  subject,  to  do  good  here, 
should  be,  not  to  render  the  slaves  discontented  but  to  shew  to  the 
whites,  of  all  classes,  the  baneful  effects  of  the  system  upon  them. 
It  is  perfectly  obvious  that  slavery  is  a  subject  placed  beyond  the 
control  of  the  General  Government  It  would  therefore  avail  but 
little,  so  long  as  this  Government  lasts,  if  every  man  north  of  Mason 
and  Dixon's  line  were  deeply  impressed  with  the  impolicy,  cruelty, 
injustice,  or  barbarity  of  slavery.  That  could  not  emancipate  one 
wretch  from  bondage.  "  Emancipation  "  can  never  be  effected  with- 
out the  consent  of  the  slaveholders,  and  this  can  never  be  obtained 
by  either  abuse  or  threats.  What  we  want  is  temperate  argument, 
going  to  shew,  the  evils  of  slavery  to  ourselves,  our  posterity,  and 
our  country;  the  superiority  in  cheapness,  convenience,  and  efficacy 
of  free  labor;  then  that  the  condition  of  the  slave  as  well  as  the 
master  would  be  improved  by  emancipation,  and  pointing  out  a 
mode  in  which  this  can  be  done  safely  without  upturning  at  once  all 
the  foundations  of  society.  Satisfy  our  people  on  these  points  and 
you  will  have  thousands  of  converts  to  emancipation.  The  fact  is 
.  .  .  [abolition  fanaticism]  .  .  .  paralizes  our  efforts.  No  friend 
of  emancipation  amongst  us,  cares  to  open  his  mouth  on  the  sub- 
ject, for  fear  of  being  branded  as  an  ally  of  Garrison,  and  of  doing 
evil  instead  of  good  to  the  cause  he  would  advocate.88 

Another  Virginian,  who  would  certainly  not  be  included 
among  her  pro-slavery  citizens,  said  of  the  Garrisonians : 

Upon  no  other  point  connected  with  slavery  have  I  ever  known 
such  unanimity  in  Virginia.  The  feeling  of  all  of  every  age,  that 
think  about  it,  is  this.  It  is  a  subject  with. which  you  shall  not  inter- 
fere; except  indeed  by  scolding  and  calling  names  at  the  distance 
of  three  hundred  miles;  and  that  if,  through  the  just  judgment  of 
Providence  on  our  land,  you  shall  ever  get  Congress  to  act  on  this 
subject,  that  moment  the  Union  is  dissolved.89 

88  Ibid.,  Edward  Colston  to  Gurley,  Martinsburg,  Va.,  July  9,  1833. 

89  Letter  to  Washington  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  W.  M.  Atkin- 
son to  Polk,  Washington,  D.  C,  January  27,  1834. 


l6o  THE  AMERICAN    COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [4/2 

Colonel  Addison  Hall  thought  in  September,  1835,  that  the 
reaction  against  abolition  excitement  had  become  so  strong 
in  Virginia  that  "  it  paralizes  all  effort.  It  would  not  only 
be  unsuccessful,  but  attended  with  personal  danger."90 
James  Garland,  a  congressmen  from  the  same  State,  who 
had  in  former  years  been  an  interested  Colonizationist, 
was  driven,  by  the  exaggerations  of  Garrisonians,  to  be- 
come an  opponent  of  even  Colonization.  In  later  years  he 
resumed  his  interest  in  the  Society,  but  against  every  Gar- 
risonion  effort  he  stood  distinctly  pledged.91  And  his  posi- 
tion on  the  subject  of  slavery  became  violently  anti-Garri- 
sonian.  A  Methodist  minister  of  New  Orleans  in  1838 
wrote  that  the  reaction  against  ultra-Abolitionism  had  had 
a  distinctly  harmful  effect  upon  the  comfort  of  the  slave, 
and  had  been  destructive  of  sentiment  favorable  to  emanci- 
pation. The  results  of  the  efforts  of  Colonizationists  had 
been  favorable  to  emancipation.92 

Francis  Scott  Key  thought  that  both  the  free  negro  and 
the  slave,  in  all  the  Middle  States,  had  been  subjected  to 
additional  restraints  directly  as  a  result  of  the  efforts  of  the 
Abolitionists.  The  efforts  of  these  agitators  he  character- 
ized as  "most  unfortunate."93  Elliot  Cresson  wrote  from 
New  Orleans :  "...  so  morbid  is  the  South  from  the  rec- 
ollection of  abolitionism,  that  it  is  scarcely  credible  how 
little  will  excite  a  storm."94  There  was  a  widespread  com- 
plaint among  the  Colonization  agents  of  the  South,  and 
among  active  Colonizationists  of  that  section,  that  this  anti- 
Garrison  feeling  had  become  so  strong  and  so  dangerous 
that  the  South  had  not  only  become  less  considerate  of  its 
slaves,  but  it  had  also  begun  to  confuse  abolition  and  colo- 
nization, looking  upon  the  latter  as  "  the  A.  B.  C.  of  Aboli- 
tion." Thousands  of  Southerners  were  undoubtedly  driven 

90  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Col.  A.  Hall  to 
Gurley,  Richmond,  Va.,  September  3,  1835. 

91  African  Repository,  vol.  xiv,  pp.  43-47. 
•  Ibid.,  vol.  xiv,  pp.  48-49. 

8  Ibid.,  vol.  xv,  p.  Ii3ff. 

94  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Cresson  to 
Wilkeson,  New  Orleans,  April  25,  1840. 


473]  COLONIZATION   AND  ABOLITION  l6l 

to  an  extreme  proslavery  position  as  a  result  of  Garrison's 
efforts.95 

Mathew  Carey,  of  Philadelphia,  and  Roger  M.  Sherman, 
of  Connecticut,  may  be  taken  as  men  of  standing  and  influ- 
ence in  the  sections  from  which  they  came.  Both  admitted 
the  sincerity  of  the  Garrisonians  and  at  the  same  time  both 
deplored  the  impolitic  and  injurious  efforts  that  those  aboli- 
tionists were  making.  Sherman  was  invited  to  attend  the 
Anti-Slavery  Convention  in  Albany,  in  1839.  I*1  m's  refusal 
to  be  present  Sherman  expressed  very  clearly  his  views: 

Had  the  Rev.  Dr.  Edwards,  and  others,  who  publicly  espoused 
measures  of  emancipation  adopted  in  Connecticut  soon  after  the 
Revolutionary  War,  called  slaveholders  Man-Stealers,  in  staring 
capitals  .  .  .  would  it  not  have  excited,  in  the  Northern  Yankees, 
more  of  resentment  than  conviction,  and  less  of  compliance  than 
opposition?  The  Southern  people  have  felt,  and  to  a  great  degree, 
justly,  that  the  Abolitionists  of  the  North  were  addressing  their 
fears;  and  not  merely  their  understandings  or  consciences.  They 
have  been  addressed  in  terms  of  opprobrious  criminations  rarely 
softened  by  the  language  of  respect.  This  has  made  them  inacces- 
sible, .  .  .  and  has,  I  fear,  put  off  emancipation  for  at  least  half  a 
century.  .  .  .  Could  a  missionary,  thus  addressing  civilized  heathen, 
hope  for  a  favourable  audience?96 

As  representatives  of  the  West,  both  Henry  Clay  and 
Elisha  Whittlesey  thought  that  the  Garrisonians  had  done 
incalculable  injury  to  both  the  white  man  and  the  slave,  and 
even  to  the  free  negro.97  A  Colonization  agent,  Rev.  M. 
M.  Henkle,  working  in  Ohio,  summed  up  the  results  of 
Abolitionism  as  follows :  "...  contributing  say  $50,000 
pr.  annum  to  inflame  the  passions  of  the  North,  wake  the 
resentments  of  the  South,  fetter  more  firmly  the  bonds  of 

95  Ibid.,  Wilkeson  to  Rev.  T.  B.  Barto,  March  27,  1840,  No.  100; 
W.  McKinney  to  McLain,  New  Bern,  N.  C,  April  15,  1840;  J.  B. 
O'Neall  to  Wilkeson,  Springfield,  S.  C.,  March  6,  1841 ;  Wm.  Crab- 
tree  to  Wilkeson,  Savannah,  Ga.,  March  10,  1841 ;  Gurley  to  R.  S. 
Marvin,  February  7,  1842,  No.  582. 

96  African  Repository,  vol.  xv,  pp.  242-244;  Letters  of  American 
Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Carey  to  Gurley,  Philadelphia,  Decem- 
ber 22,  1829. 

97  African  Repository,  vol.  xii,  pp.   10-12 ;  Letters  of  American 
Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Whittlesey  to  Wilkeson,  Canfield,  Ohio, 
March  16,  1840. 

II 


1 62  THE  AMERICAN    COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [4/4 

the  slave,  and  strain  the  tender  ligaments  of  the  political 
Union,  to  the  last  stretch  of  endurance.  .  .  ."98 

The  most  conclusive  and  interesting  proof  that  Coloni- 
zation had  an  influence  beneficial  and  pronounced  upon 
public  sentiment  at  the  South,  and  particularly  upon  slave- 
holders, is  contained  in  a  study  of  emancipations  that  were 
brought  about  by  the  influence  of  the  Society."  But — and 
on  this  point  present  day  writers  have  failed  to  do  justice 
to  the  Society  in  their  estimates  of  its  importance — the  effect 
upon  public  opinion  is  not  to  be  measured  alone  in  the  num- 
ber of  emancipations  effected  or  the  size  of  the  colony  estab- 
lished. By  far  the  most  important  influence  the  organiza- 
tion exerted  prior  to  1845  was  its  influence  upon  public 
opinion  on  the  question  of  slavery.  That  influence  was 
positive,  though  in  large  measure  intangible  and  immaterial. 

That  between  1830  and  1840  the  Colonizationists  were 
drawing  public  sentiment,  from  New  Orleans  to  Vermont, 
to  a  common  view  of  the  best  solution  of  the  whole  negro 
problem,  there  is  abundant  evidence.  In  1832  Dr.  John 
Ker  reported  a  large  part  of  the  most  prominent  political 
figures  of  Louisiana  favorable  to  the  colonization  mode  of 
dealing  with  slavery  and  the  free  negro.100  In  the  same 
year,  the  Colonizationists  were  making  their  way  into  the 
confidence  and  were  gaining  the  support  of  important  offi- 
cials in  Virginia.101  In  1834  there  were  still  citizens  of 
Vermont  who  were  willing  and  anxious  to  meet  their  breth- 
ren from  New  Orleans,  and  settle  the  slavery  question  on 
the  terms  proposed  by  the  Colonizationists.102  In  1837,  a 
joint  committee  of  the  Illinois  legislature  unanimously  ap- 
proved the  colonization  method,  as  had  the  officials  of 
Louisiana  and  the  citizens  of  Vermont.  The  Colonization 
societies,  in  their  opinion,  "were  silently,  but  surely  winning 

88  Letters    of   American    Colonization    Society,    MS.,   Henkle   to 
Gurley,  Cincinnati,  Ohio,  June  18,  1838. 

99  See  chapter  below  on  Colonization  and  Emancipation,  passim. 

100  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Ker  to  Gu-r- 
ley,  New  Orleans,  April  4,  1832. 

101  Ibid.,  Atkinson  to  Gurley,  Petersburg,  Va.,  July  27,  1832. 

102  African  Repository,  vol.  x,  p.  148. 


475]  COLONIZATION   AND  ABOLITION  1 63 

their  way  upon  public  opinion,  and  entwining  powerfully 
around  the  affections  of  the  people."  As  to  the  Abolition- 
ists, they  "have  forged  new  irons  for  the  black  man,  and 
added  an  hundred  fold  to  the  rigor  of  slavery.  They  have 
scattered  the  firebrands  of  discord  and  disunion  among  the 
different  states  of  the  confederacy/'  The  Colonization 
scheme  was  their  choice.103  In  1838  the  Southern  Literary 
Messenger  was  satisfied  with  the  Colonization  scheme  as 
being  the  "juste  milieu,"  "the  bread  platform  upon  which 
the  friends  of  this  unhappy  race  may  meet  in  soberness  and 
safety."104  And  in  1840  the  committee  of  the  Pennsylvania 
Legislature,  to  which  the  matter  had  been  referred,  reported 
colonization  to  be,  in  their  opinion,  "the  only  mode  by  which 
an  equality  of  rights  can  be  secured  to  that  unfortunate  race 
[the  negro]  ."105 

Next,  as  to  the  results  of  Abolition  and  Colonization  upon 
those  religious  bodies  whose  influence  and  organization  ex- 
tended throughout  the  Union.  It  has  already  been  seen 
that  before  the  rise  of  Garrisonism,  there  was  great  una- 
nimity of  sentiment  in  favor  of  Colonization  among  nearly 
all  religious  denominations.  Again  and  again  the  Metho- 
dist church  passed  resolutions  in  its  national  gatherings 
warmly  recommending  the  cause  to  the  attention  of  its  min- 
istry. The  same  was  true  of  the  Presbyterian  and  of  the 
Baptist  churches.  But  as  has  also  been  seen,  one  of  the 
most  significant  changes  of  sentiment  brought  about  by  Gar- 
rison's efforts  was  the  change  in  the  position  New  England 
churches  took  between  1831  and  1845.  In  1831  public 
opinion  was  being  led  by  sentiment  in  the  churches ;  in  1845 
public  opinion  was  leading  sentiment  in  the  churches. 

A  study  of  the  division  of  the  Methodist  church,  1844- 
1845,  is  of  peculiar  interest  as  exhibiting  this  change  of  sen- 
timent that  had  been  going  on  at  the  North.  In  1834  a 
Methodist  Conference,  sitting  at  New  Haven,  Connecticut, 

108  Ibid.,  vol.  xiii,  pp.  109-111. 

104  Ibid.,  vol.  xiv,  p.  308. 

105  Ibid.,  vol.  xvi,  pp.  136-137. 


164  THE   AMERICAN    COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [476 

recommended  the  Colonization  movement,  and  deplored  the 
opposition  of  the  Abolitionists,  as  "directly  calculated  to 
injure  the  best  interest  of  colored  men,  whether  bond  or 
free,"  and  also  calculated  to  have  the  "most  unfavorable 
results  "  upon  the  progress  of  Christian  principles.106  And 
yet,  just  ten  years  later,  the  organization  of  the  Methodist 
church  was  rent  in  twain,  and  the  territory  from  Maryland 
to  the  Gulf  of  Mexico  came  under  the  jurisdiction  of  the 
Southern  Methodist  Church.  There  has  been  much  dis- 
cussion upon  the  causes  of  that  division;  but  the  leading 
cause  seems  to  the  writer  to  be  almost  obvious,  when  viewed 
in  the  light  of  the  attitude  each  section  of  that  church  took 
toward  the  Abolition  and  Colonization  societies.  It  is  uni- 
versally admitted  that  the  question  of  slavery  was  almost 
the  sole  cause  of  the  disruption  of  that  church.  But  was 
it  the  attitude  of  the  Northern  Methodists  or  of  the  South- 
ern Methodists  that  brought  about  the  division?  In  1834 
united  Methodism  was  very  favorable  to  the  Colonization 
scheme.  In  1845  the  Southern  Methodists  were  still  favor- 
able to  it;  but  the  Northern  Methodists  had  come  so  far 
under  the  influence  of  Garrison,  or  they  had  been  so  far 
carried  away  from  their  position  of  ten  years  before  by  the 
tide  of  public  sentiment,  that,  either  because  the  majority 
of  Northern  Methodists  had  become  Garrisonian  or  at  least 
aggressively  Abolitionist,  or  else  because  so  strong  a  mi- 
nority of  them  had  gone  over  to  that  party,  they  forced  the 
Northern  majority  by  a  threat  of  secession  from  them  and 
secured  the  passage  of  a  resolution  whose  effect  was  prac- 
tically to  suspend  a  Southern  Bishop  who  had  inherited  two 
slaves. 

The  fact  is  that  the  Southern  Methodist  Church  in  1845 
retained  the  same  good  feeling  for  Colonization  that  it  had 
in  1835 ;  but  the  Northern  section  of  Methodism  had  been 
borne  away  on  the  tide  of  Abolitionism.  Whatever  may  be 
said  about  the  legal  forms  the  separation  took,  and  whether 
by  the  acts  of  separation  the  Southerners  seceded  from  the 

106  Ibid.,  vol.  x,  p.  127. 


477]  COLONIZATION   AND  ABOLITION  165 

general  body  or  the  general  body  seceded  from  the  South- 
erners, or  whether  the  separation  was  completely  by  agree- 
ment— neither  church  seceding,  but  both  agreeing  peaceably 
to  separate — it  is  nevertheless  a  matter  of  fact  that  in  terms 
of  ultimate  and  real  causes,  the  Northern  Methodists 
changed  radically  their  views  while  those  of  the  Southern 
Methodists  remained  practically  what  they  had  been  in 
1834.  In  1835  both  Northern  and  Southern  Methodists 
were,  as  a  body,  opposed  to  radical  Abolitionism.  In  1845 
the  Southern  Methodists  were  still  opposed  to  it ;  while  the 
majority,  or  a  commanding  minority  of  the  Methodists  of 
the  North  had  become  favorable  to  it.  In  1835  Northern 
and  Southern  Methodists  warmly  recommended  the  Colo- 
nization Society.  In  1845  ft  was  the  Southern  church  that 
warmly  recommended  it.  That  year  the  Mississippi  Con- 
ference of  the  Southern  Methodist  Church  unanimously 
adopted  a  resolution  commending  the  cause  of  Coloni- 
zation.107 

Northern  Methodists  had  been  drawn  away  from  their 
former  ground  by  the  tide  of  public  sentiment;  Southern 
Methodists  remained  where  they  had  stood  ten  years  be- 
fore. And  George  F.  Pierce,  later  Bishop  Pierce,  was  right 
in  declaring  at  the  General  Conference  of  1844:  "The  diffi- 
culties are  with  the  New  Englanders.  They  are  making 
all  this  difficulty.  .  .  ."108  Indeed,  the  Northern  section  of 
the  church  had  gone  so  rapidly  to  the  position  of  the  Aboli- 
tionists that  they  were  ahead  of  the  regulations  of  their 
book  of  discipline.  There  had  been  no  disciplinary  rule 
adopted  by  which  a  slaveholding  bishop  could  be  suspended 
from  the  exercise  of  his  functions;  and  the  resolution  of 
suspension  was  adopted  largely,  it  seems,  as  a  matter  of 
expediency,  to  prevent  the  secession  of  the  whole  of  New 
England  Methodism.109  Either  because  of  its  own  convic- 
tions, or  to  save  to  itself  New  England  Methodism,  the 

107  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Pinney  to  Mc- 
Lain,  New  Orleans,  December  13,  1845 ;  December  14,  1845. 

108  G.  G.  Smith,  Life  and  Times  of  George  F.  Pierce,  chap.  vi. 
*»  Ibid. 


1 66  THE  AMERICAN   COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [478 

Methodist  Episcopal  Church  changed  its  attitude  and  thus 
abandoned  the  ground  it  had  held  in  common  with  Southern 
Methodism.110  Few  Virginians  in  1846  were  more  ardent 
Colonizationists  than  Bishop  John  Early,  president  of  the 
Petersburg  Colonization  Society.  And  that  year  both  bishops 
of  the  Southern  Church  were  Colonizationists,111  as  were 
leading  Southern  Methodist  ministers,  like  William  Winans 
of  Mississippi,  or  John  E.  Edwards  of  Richmond. 

One  can  without  difficulty  recognize  the  meat  upon  which 
the  New  Hampshire  minister  fed  who,  in  advocating  the 
resolution  which  brought  about  the  division  of  the  Metho- 
dist Church,  declared :  "  Men-buyers  are  exactly  on  a  level 
with  men-stealers."112  That  was  not  the  spirit  of  Coloniza- 
tion ;  it  was  the  spirit  of  Garrisonian  Abolition.  It  rent  in 
twain  other  religious  bodies.  And  it  was  because  Garri- 
sonian Abolition  was  fundamentally  and  essentially  destruc- 
tive of  economic,  social,  political,  and  religious  national 
unity.  The  influence  of  Colonization  was  exactly  the  re- 
verse. We  have  seen  its  unifying  influence  in  our  study 
of  its  effect  upon  the  public  opinion  of  the  United  States. 
It  was  so  in  society.  It  was  distinctly  so  in  the  church. 

Finally,  in  comparing  the  methods  and  results  of  Garri- 
sonian Abolition  and  the  Colonization  Society,  it  may  be 
interesting  to  look  for  a  while  at  the  interchange  of  views 
that  was  taking  place  among  Colonization  leaders,  and  see 
how  far  those  views  will  aid  us  in  refuting  the  oft-repeated 
charges  of  the  Garrisonians  that,  after  all,  Colonization  was 
an  enormous  obstacle  in  the  way  of  emancipation,  and  that 
its  ally  was  the  slaveholder. 

As  early  as  1828  Elliot  Cresson  was  urging  upon  the  Sec- 
retary of  the  Colonization  Society  the  importance  of  hearty 
cooperation  between  the  Abolitionists  and  Colonization- 

110  African  Repository,  vol.  xix,  p.  252. 

111  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  T.  C.  Benn;ng 
to  McLain,  Petersburg,  Va.,  May  5,  1846 ;  Rev.  J.  E.  Edwards,  Rich- 
mond, Va.,  May  25,  1846. 

112  Smith,  p.  123. 


479]  COLONIZATION  AND  ABOLITION  l6/ 

ists.113  In  1831  one  of  the  largest  contributors  to  the  So- 
ciety in  Kentucky  was  a  man  who  had  liberated  his  slaves 
and  for  five  years  refused  to  eat  with  a  slaveholder,  espe- 
cially if  he  were  a  Methodist.114  Robert  J.  Breckenridge, 
of  Kentucky,  had  made  great  sacrifice  of  reputation  in 
order  to  aid  the  Colonization  Society  to  hasten  the  day  of 
general  emancipation  in  his  State.115  William  M.  Black- 
ford,  a  leader  among  Colonizationists  of  Eastern  Virginia, 
expressed  himself  as  follows  on  the  subject  of  slavery: 

We  have  had  reason  to  curse  slavery  within  the  last  day  or  two, 
from  a  painful  exemplification  of  it's  evils  occurring  under  our  own 
eyes.  A  year  ago  I  bought  [and  therefore,  by  the  reasoning  of  the 
Abolitionists,  he  was  a  man-stealer]  a  negro  woman  from  a  trader, 
to  prevent  her  separation  from  her  husband.  She  was  truly  grati- 
fied and  has  made  us  a  faithful  servant  ever  since.  Her  husband 
belonged  to  an  estate.  In  dividing  it,  a  sale  became  necessary,  and 
without  letting  me  know  of  it,  he  was  sold  to  a  trader.  He  was 
seized  on  the  streets,  handcuffed,  and  then  permitted  to  take  leave 
of  his  wife.  He  entered  our  yard,  crying,  and  presented  himself 
in  that  situation  to  his  wife,  who  had  not  the  remotest  idea  of  such 
an  event.  I  leave  you  to  imagine  the  feelings  of  his  wife —  and  also 
of  Mrs.  Bflackford].  It  has  prayed  upon  the  latter's  mind  very 
much,  and  will,  I  fear,  make  her  sick.  The  man  was  addicted  to 
drink,  but  was  civil  and  industrious,  and  made  an  affectionate  hus- 
band. But  I  needn't  pain  you  by  reflections  on  this  subject.116 

J.  Burton  Harrison  expressed  the  hope  of  Colonization- 
ists generally  when  he  wrote :  "  I  am  firmly  persuaded  that 
Kentucky  is  the  most  hopeful  of  all  the  slaveholding  States 
(let  me  call  them  'transition'  States  which  seem  not  de- 
voted to  slavery  in  perpetuity,  as  Maryland,  Virginia,  Ken- 
tucky, and  perhaps  others)  except  Maryland."117  A  letter 
which  is  typical  of  scores  of  letters  that  were  sent  out  to 
the  Society's  friends  from  the  central  office,  contains  the 
following:  "We  must  if  possible  start  a  ship  next  month. 
About  40  liberated  slaves  are  now  waiting  and  must  be  sent 

118  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Cresson  to 
Gurley,  Philadelphia,  August  23,  1828. 

114  Ibid.,  Finley  to  Gurley,  Winchester,  Ky.,  June  8,  1831. 

115  Ibid.,  R.  J.  Breckenridge  to  Gurley,  Lexington,  Ky.,  August 
16,  1831. 

118  Ibid.,  W.  M.  Blackford  to  Gurley,  Fredericksburg,  Va.,  Octo- 
ber 4,  1832. 
117  Ibid.,  Harrison  to  Gurley,  New  Orleans,  May  16,  1833. 


1 68  THE  AMERICAN    COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [480 

or  sold  for  the  South!"11*  John  McDonogh,  one  of  the 
foremost  Colonizationists  of  Louisiana,  sought  from  the 
legislature  of  that  State  permission  to  educate  his  slaves — 
for  it  was  against  the  law  for  him  to  do  so  without  obtain- 
ing permission  from  the  legislature.  He  owned  slaves 
valued  at  $150,000.00,  and  it  was  his  purpose  to  colonize 
them  all  in  Liberia,  as  they  gave  evidence  of  the  ability  to 
care  for  themselves.119  Gerrit  Smith,  who  would  hardly  be, 
by  any  student  of  Abolition,  accused  of  pro-slavery  leaning, 
wrote,  in  1828,  concerning  the  alarm  among  slaveholders 
suspicious  of  the  Colonization  Society:  "I  must  think  that 
our  slaveholders  are  causelessly  alarmed  at  the  American 
Colonization  Society."120  He  realized  perfectly  well  that 
the  sympathetic  attitude  the  Society  assumed  in  its  official 
journal  towards  the  slaveholder  was  assumed,  not  out  of  a 
love  for  slavery,  but  out  of  a  belief  that  the  only  way  to 
persuade  the  slaveholder  to  emancipate  his  slaves  was  to 
secure  first  his  friendship  and  respect  and,  as  a  result,  the 
liberation  of  his  slaves.121 

Of  course  it  was  no  difficult  matter  for  the  Abolitionists 
to  take  these  very  sympathetic  utterances  and  build  up  a 
conclusive  argument  setting  forth  the  base  motives  of  Colo- 
nizationists. And  they  did  so,  although  the  motive  that 
they  "proved"  was  exactly  the  opposite  of  that  which  the 
Colonizationists  actually  had.  What  was  used  as  a  bait  to 
to  secure  the  liberation  of  slaves  was  pictured  by  the  Garri- 
sonians  to  be  the  outcropping  of  the  evil  spirit  back  of  the 
scheme.  And  yet  a  fair  statement  of  its  position  was  fre- 
quently made  to  the  public  in  the  African  Repository.  For 
instance,  in  1830  it  was  there  stated:  "That  the  system  of 
slavery  must  exist  temporarily  in  this  country,  we  as  firmly 

118  Ibid.,  McLain  to  Mrs.  Ann  Richardson,  November  14,  1840. 
110  African  Repository,  vol.  x,  p.  24. 

120  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Smith  to  Gur- 
ley,  November  17,  1828. 

121  Ibid.,  Smith  to  Gurley,  Peterboro,  N.  Y.,  Feb.  6,  1831. 


481]  COLONIZATION   AND   ABOLITION  169 

believe,  as  that  for  its  existence  a  single  moment,  there  can 
be  offered  justly  no  plea  but  necessity."122 

It  was  reasonably  conclusive  proof  both  of  the  sincerity 
of  the  Society  and  of  the  effectiveness  of  its  methods  that 
Francis  Scott  Key,  appealing  to  Philadelphia  for  funds,  re- 
ported that  more  than  six  hundred  slaves  were  at  that  time 
offered  by  slaveholders  on  the  condition  of  their  removal  to 
Liberia,  and  that  only  the  funds  were  needed  to  secure  their 
immediate  liberation.123 

While  the  appointment  of  Dr.  Ezekiel  Skinner  as  colonial 
agent  was  under  consideration,  he  thought  wise  to  make 
clear  his  position  on  the  subject  of  slavery.  It  was  this: 

I  have  ever  held  slavery  in  abomination  as  the  blackest  of  the 
black  catalogue  of  human  crimes,  the  criminality  of  which  is  not  in 
the  least  lessened  by  the  authority  of  human  laws  and  which  will 
carry  the  souls  of  those  who  are  guilty  of  this  crime  before  the 
bar  of  God  blacker  with  moral  pollution  than  the  skins  of  those 
whom  they  unjustly  held  in  bondage. 

I  am  friendly  to  the  Colonization  Society  as  presenting  the  only 
means  now  with  [in]  our  power  to  emancipate  many  whom  we  have 
reason  to  believe  would  otherwise  die  in  slavery.12* 

This  statement  caused  neither  a  withdrawal  of  his  appoint- 
ment nor  criticism  of  his  position. 

At  the  annual  meeting  of  the  Society  in  1834,  Brecken- 
ridge  thus  stated  the  position  of  Colonizationists  in  their 
relation  to  the  slaveholder:  "We  stand  in  the  breach  for 
him,  to  keep  off  the  Abolitionists.  We  are  his  friends,  but 
only  to  give  him  time.  .  .  .  And  if  he  attempts  to  maintain 
slavery  as  perpetual,  every  one  of  us  will  be  upon  him  too." 
At  the  same  meeting  Gerrit  Smith  reviewed  several  of  the 
charges  made  against  the  Society,  among  which  was  the 
charge  that  there  were  at  that  time  265,000  persons  "now 
in  slavery,  who  would  have  been  free  if  it  had  not  been  for 
the  influence  of  this  Society."  A  second  charge  was  that 
all  colonies  whatever  on  the  Coast  of  Africa  went  to  sup- 

121  African  Repository,  vol.  v,  pp.  328-330;  Letters  of  American 
Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Gurley  to  Fendall,  New  York,  Novem- 
ber 4,  1833- 

28  African  Repository,  vol.  vi,  pp.  138-139. 

12*  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  E.  Skinner  to 
Gurley,  Ashford,  Conn.,  January  23,  1834. 


I7O  THE  AMERICAN    COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [482 

port,  rather  than  suppress  the  slave  trade.  In  its  review 
of  the  speech,  The  Liberator  maintained  that  both  these 
charges  were  true.125  It  is  an  interesting  fact  that  at  that 
meeting  it  was  a  resident  of  Connecticut  who  urged  the 
Society  to  confine  its  efforts  chiefly  to  the  transportation  of 
free  blacks,  touching  the  question  of  slavery  and  emancipa- 
tion as  lightly  as  possible ;  and  it  was  a  resident  of  Mary- 
land who  urged  that  it  concentrate  its  efforts  upon  trans- 
porting to  the  colony  slaves  emancipated  for  that  express 
purpose — in  short,  that  it  become  more  pronouncedly  a 
society  whose  purpose  was  the  liberation  of  slaves. 

Dr.  Reese,  one  of  the  most  prominent  members  of  the 
New  York  City  Colonization  Society,  thus  expressed  him- 
self on  his  attitude  towards  slavery :  "  Sir,  I  abhor  slavery, 
and  therefore  am  I  a  friend  of  Colonization.  .  .  .  If  slavery 
should  not  eventually,  under  the  influence  of  kindness  and 
confidence,  be  abolished,  it  would  be  because  the  visionaries 
of  the  North  would  prevent  it."120 

If  there  was  ever  a  time  when  the  Colonizationists  were 
unscrupulously  assailed  from  both  the  press  and  the  plat- 
form of  the  Garrisonians,  that  time  was  from  1831  to  1840. 
R.  R.  Gurley,  Secretary  of  the  Society,  saw  more  and  knew 
more  of  that  storm  than  did  any  other  individual.  During 
that  period  the  Society's  purposes  were  continually  misrep- 
resented, and  Gurley  knew,  for  he  directed,  the  movements 
and  efforts  of  the  organization.  In  a  number  of  personal 
letters  written  to  members  of  the  Board  of  Managers  dur- 
ing this  period,  Gurley  sets  forth  clearly  both  his  own  views 
and  the  views  of  those  Colonizationists  with  whom  he 
talked  as  he  traveled  for  the  Society  from  Massachusetts 
to  Georgia. 

Of  the  influence  of  colonization  in  Maryland  he  writes: 
"In  Maryland,  the  spirit  of  Colonization  is  increasing 
among  the  slaveholders  and  no  difficulty  is  experienced  in 

125  The  Liberator,  Feb.  8,  1834.    Here  will  be  found  an  account 
of  the  speeches  made  at  this  important  meeting  of  the  Society. 
128  Ibid.,  May  24,  1834. 


483]  COLONIZATION   AND  ABOLITION  I/ 1 

procuring  emigrants  of  the  best  character,  out  of  the  city 
of  Balto."127  Of  his  hopes  for  Virginia  he  writes :  "  I  trust 
Virginia  will  receive  the  special  attention  of  the  Board. 
Let  her  voice  be  with  us ;  let  her  consent  that  Congress  shall 
appropriate  money  to  colonisation  and  we  have  triumphed 
— slavery  will  go  down  with  the  consent  of  the  South,  and 
the  Union  will  be  preserved."128  And  again:  "The  people 
of  the  South  must  look  to  the  Colonization  policy  as  to  the 
sheet  anchor  of  their  safety.  Can  they  be  so  blind  as  not 
to  see  or  so  destitute  of  wisdom  as  not  to  prepare  for  the 
gathering  storm?  Can  the  South  be  induced  to  propose 
and  support  Colonization  as  a  National  measure  looking  to 
the  final  abolition  of  slavery?  Will  Virginia  lead  in  the 
scheme?  If  so,  all  is  safe."129  Or  again:  "Let  it  be  ours 
to  bind  together  all  the  moderate  and  sober  friends  of  Lib- 
erty and  Africa  in  the  Union."130  After  a  journey  into 
Louisiana  and  Mississippi,  where  several  large  bequests  had 
recently  been  made  for  the  Society,  he  commented :  "  Each 
successive  year,  hereafter,  will  bequests  to  our  Institution 
be  multiplying  and  increasing,  thousands  of  slaves  will  be 
placed  under  the  protection  of  the  Society,  and  all  motives 
concur  to  urge  us  to  adopt  all  proper  methods  ...  to  en- 
able us  to  secure  such  bequests  and  the  freedom  and  colo- 
nization of  such  slaves,  as  may  be  entrusted  to  our  care."131 
Kentucky,  he  thought,  had  proved  a  profitable  field  for 
Colonization  effort,  and  he  believed  that  the  result  was  a 
rapidly  growing  disposition  among  her  slaveholders  to  lib- 
erate their  slaves,  on  condition  of  their  emigration  to  the 
colony.182 

Whether  or  not  the  very  advocacy  of  gradual  emancipa- 
tion was  of  itself  a  hindrance  to  immediate  emancipation 
there  might  be,  and  doubtless  was  wide  difference  of  opin- 

127  Letters   of    American    Colonization    Society,   MS.,   Gurley   to 
Fendall,  Boston,  August  3,  1835. 

128  Ibid.,  Gurley  to  Gales,  Boston,  Oct.  3,  1835. 

129  Ibid.,  confidential,  Gurley  to  Fendall,  Boston,  October  7,  1835. 

180  Ibid.,  Gurley  to  Gales,  Philadelphia,  December  12,  1835. 

181  Ibid.,  Gurley  to  Gales,  Louisville,  Ky.,  July  25,  1836. 

182  Ibid.,  Gurley  to  Fendall,  Athens,  Ga.,  June  7,  1837. 


172  THE  AMERICAN   COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [484 

ion.  If  Abolitionists  had  urged  this  as  the  inevitable  result 
of  any  scheme  of  gradual  emancipation,  the  Colonizationists 
could  have  had  no  just  quarrel.  Such  a  question  might 
have  been  threshed  out  on  the  battleground  of  reason.  The 
great  blunder  the  Garrisonians  made  was  not  in  arguing 
that  the  tendency  of  Colonization  was  necessarily  to  put  off 
the  hoped-for  day,  but  that  it  was  the  deliberate  purpose  of 
Colonizationists  to  put  off  that  day.  There  have  been 
found,  among  the  records  of  the  Colonization  Society,  prior 
to  1846,  two  letters  which  go  to  show  that  the  members  of 
one  auxiliary  Colonization  Society,  in  Tennessee,  and  a 
number  of  lukewarm  friends  of  the  cause  in  Alabama  based 
their  support  of  Colonization  upon  the  ground,  either  of  its 
usefulness  as  an  ally  of  the  slaveholder,  in  removing  the 
distracting  free  blacks  from  the  possibility  of  their  influence 
over  the  slaves,  or  of  its  usefulness  in  relieving  a  section 
undoubtedly  burdened  with  free  blacks.133  And  the  writer 
of  the  letter  from  Alabama  understood  well  enough  the  true 
objects  of  Colonizationists,  to  accuse  his  neighbors  of 
"  Machiavelism."  Voluminous  evidence,  forsooth,  upon 
which  to  make  out  a  case  for  the  Garrisonians ! 

It  would  not  be  difficult  to  show  that  there  were  cases  in 
which  the  Garrisonians  themselves  prevented  emancipa- 
tions. In  1839,  for  instance,  a  Colonization  agent  was  ap- 
proached by  a  Kentucky  slaveholder,  who  desired  to  eman- 
cipate his  twenty  slaves,  giving  them  five  hundred  dollars, 
on  condition  of  their  willingness  to  go  to  Liberia.  Upon 
invitation,  the  agent  addressed  the  slaves  and  secured  their 
consent  to  go.  But  the  next  morning  they  had  all,  save  one, 
changed  their  minds.  The  cause  of  this  change  the  master 
attributed  (i)  to  the  influence  of  the  Garrisonians,  who 
continually  reminded  the  slaves  that  the  Colonizationists 
desired  to  "banish"  them,  or  to  "expatriate"  them,  and 
(2)  to  the  rumors  that  had  come  to  them  of  violent  cases 
of  seasickness  and  deaths,  which,  with  the  rest,  the  Garri- 

188  Ibid.,  H.  A.  Wise  to  Gurley,  Nashville,  Tenn.,  January  9,  1830; 
W.  C.  Dennis  to  Gurley,  Blakeley,  Ala.,  December  21,  1838. 


485]  COLONIZATION   AND  ABOLITION 

sonians  did  not  hesitate  to  publish.134  In  1840  the  executor 
of  Thomas  Hall  of  Virginia  who,  by  his  will  liberated  some 
twenty-five  of  his  slaves — each  to  be  given  twenty-five  dol- 
lars if  he  agreed  to  go  to  the  colony,  and  those  refusing  to 
go  to  revert  to  slavery — in  reporting  those  who  desired  to 
emigrate,  expressed  his  desire  to  go  about  through  the  com- 
munity and  solicit  from  his  neighbors  subscriptions  to  in- 
crease the  allowance  of  the  negroes  who  were  about  to 
leave ;  but  he  was  prevented  from  doing  so  "by  the  wretched 
policy  of  the  abolitionists,"  who  had  "created  a  prejudice 
against  even  colonization  here,  that  threatens  all  hope  of 
carrying  on  its  operations  south  of  Mason  and  Dixon's  line. 
A  man  is  in  danger  of  being  charged  with  a  leaning  to  aboli- 
tion if  he  advances  Colonization/'135 

Such  examples  could  be  multiplied  many  times,  and  yet, 
it  would  be  manifestly  unfair  to  argue  that  the  Garrisonians 
were  opponents  of  emancipation.  The  charges  of  the  Gar- 
risonians were  every  whit  as  unfair.  There  were  those  in 
Kentucky  who  believed  that,  but  for  the  extreme  and  radi- 
cal opposition  of  the  Abolitionists  to  Colonization,  Ken- 
tucky would  by  1840  have  been  practically  ready  to  pass  a 
general  emancipation  law.  And  of  a  large  number  of  slaves 
owned  by  Mr.  Black  of  Tennessee,  and  offered  to  the  So- 
ciety upon  certain  conditions,  but  who  had  fallen  into  the 
hands  of  ill-disposed  heirs  and  sold  to  the  Southwest,  Sec- 
retary McLain  wrote:  "We  begged  hard  for  them  but  the 
country  did  not  respond  and  now  they  are  beyond  our  reach 
— and  involved  in  perpetual  slavery."136  May  it  not  be 
asked  whether  some  of  the  money  used  in  spreading  base- 
less slanders  against  the  Colonization  Society  might  not 
profitably  have  been  used  in  contributions  to  that  Society, 
to  secure  the  liberation  of  proffered  slaves  ? 

A  leading  minister  of  Mississippi  declared,  in  New  York, 
that  the  Colonization  Society  had  had  a  tremendous  influ- 

184  Ibid.,  G.  W.  Fagg  to  Wilkeson,  Elizabethtown,  Ky.,  Septem- 
ber 19,  1839. 

135  Ibid.,  E.  Broadus  to  Wilkeson,  Culpeper,  Va.,  August  II,  1840. 

136  Ibid.,  Cresson,  Washington,  June  3,  1844. 


THE   AMERICAN    COLONIZATION    SOCIETY  [486 

ence  in  preparing  the  way  for  the  opening  of  the  door  of  a 
gradual,  but  complete  emancipation  in  that  State,  but  that 
the  rise  of  rabid  Garrisonism  had  been  one  of  the  foremost 
agents  in  closing  "  every  door  that  had  been  opened  for  the 
escape  of  the  slave.  .  .  ."1S7  A  plain  miller  of  eastern  Vir- 
ginia, not  troubled  with  the  "  too  liberal  construction  "  fears 
of  his  more  learned  fellow  citizens,  wrote  to  the  Society, 
requesting  the  transportation  of  his  family  of  six  slaves, 
and  expressed  the  opinion  that,  if  the  federal  government 
and  the  Abolitionists  would  cooperate  with  Colonizationists, 
they  could  "  heal  a  disease  that,  if  not  arrested,  is  likely  to 
dissolve  the  Union."138  From  these  evidences  it  seems  clear 
that  among  the  results  of  Garrisonian  Abolition  in  the 
South  are  to  be  mentioned  not  only  a  change  very  unfavor- 
able to  voluntary  emancipation,  but  also  a  large  number  of 
instances  of  actual  prevention  of  immediate  emancipation. 
And  yet  it  would  obviously  do  violence  to  the  true  interpre- 
tation of  the  Garrisonian  faith  to  accuse  its  representatives 
of  hostility  to  the  immediate  emancipation  of  slaves. 

J.  G.  Birney,  at  this  time  an  agent  of  the  Colonization 
Society  and  soon  to  become  Abolitionist,  gives  an  interest- 
ing summary  of  his  view  on  prospects  in  the  South.  These 
views  are  entitled  to  considerable  weight,  in  the  light  of 
Birney's  later  prominence  in  political  abolition  and  his  place 
in  the  Liberal  Party.  In  1833,  he  wrote,  of  the  prospects 
of  getting  rid  of  slavery  in  the  slaveholding  States: 

The  only  effectual  way  that  seems  open  to  my  view,  is  the  with- 
drawing of  Virginia  from  the  Slave  States,  by  her  adoption  of  some 
scheme  of  emancipation.  Should  this  be  done,  the  whole  system  of 
slavery  in  the  U.  S.  would,  upon  the  very  pressure  of  public  opinion, 
be  brought,  and  that  in  a  few  years,  in  shivers  to  the  ground.  In 
proportion  as  the  slaveholding  territory  is  weakened  in  political 
influence,  it  will  be  weakened  in  the  power  of  withstanding  the  force 
of  public  sentiment;  and  the  last  State  in  which  slavery  shall  exist 
.  .  .  will  ...  be  perfectly  odious.  (The  proceedings  of  the  Aboli- 
tionists of  the  North  have  a  very  injurious  effect  here — they  seem 
to  furnish  a  kind  of  justification  of  slavery  itself  to  the  Southern 
slaveholders.  I  assure  you,  sir,  I  have  nothing  left  but  hope  for 

137  African  Repository,  vol.  xx,  p.  183. 

188  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  John  Gray  to 
McLain,  Fredericksburg,  Va.,  January  27,  1845. 


487]  COLONIZATION   AND  ABOLITION  175 

the  South.  By  the  word  South,  I  mean  South — Ala.,  Miss*.,  Louo. 
In  20  years  they  must  be  overrun  by  the  blacks.  There  is  no  escape 
but  in  doing  that,  which,  I  am  almost  certain,  will  not  be  done.) 
What  I  would  now  suggest,  would  be  to  press  with  every  energy 
upon  Maryland,  Virgo,  and  Ky.  for  emancipation  and  colonization. 
If  Virga.  be  not  detached  from  the  number  of  slavehplding  States, 
the  slavery  question  must  inevitably  dissolve  the  Union,  and  that 
before  very  long.  Should  she  leave  them,  the  Union  will  be  safe, 
tho'  the  suffering  of  the  South  will  be  almost  unto  death.  ...  I 
greatly  approve  of  your  opinion,  that  "  for  some  years,  at  least,  the 
North  should  forbear,"  that  everything  that  looks  like  relief  for 
the  South  may  be  attempted.139 

Two  and  a  half  months  later  he  wrote  again : 

I  do  not  believe,  that  anything  effectual  can  be  done  South  of 
Tennessee.  In  the  spirit  of  emancipation  which  the  colonization 
cause  has  produced,  the  planters  of  the  South  see  that  it  does  affect 
the  subject  of  slavery.  This  they  are  determined  not  to  have 
touched  in  any  way.  It  is  my  sincere  belief  that  the  South — at 
least  that  part  of  it  in  which  I  have  been  operating  has,  within  the 
last  year,  become  very  manifestly,  more  and  more  indurated  upon 
the  subject  of  slavery.140 

It  was  precisely  this  hope  of  winning  the  Middle  States, 
that  continued  to  permit  slavery,  and  thus  to  win  its  way 
further  and  further  down  into  the  lower  South,  all  the  while 
making  whatever  efforts  it  could  in  the  newer  Southwestern 
States,  that  actuated  the  Colonization  Society.  With  Vir- 
ginia, Maryland,  Kentucky,  and  Tennessee  among  the  free 
States,  the  pressure  of  public  opinion  and  the  futility  of 
physical  opposition  would  make  the  entire  Union  some  day, 
without  a  national  upheaval,  free  from  the  blight  of  slavery. 
In  the  language  of  Francis  Scott  Key:  "No  slave  State 
adjacent  to  a  free  State  can  continue  so."141  It  was  always 
in  these  "  adjacent "  States  that  the  condition  of  the  slaves 
was  least  undesirable,  and  hence,  in  which  the  accusations  of 
the  Garrisonians  were  most  unfounded  in  fact.  It  was  here 
also  that  the  influence  of  the  Garrisonians  reached  most 
directly,  and  where  the  reaction  against  both  Abolition  and 
Colonization,  on  account  of  the  Abolitionists,  was,  if  not 
more  defiant,  nevertheless  most  destructive. 

If  the  sincerity  of  the  Colonization  cause,  which  the  Gar- 

188  Ibid.,  Birney  to  Gurley,  Huntsville,  Ala.,  September  14,  1833. 

140  Ibid.,  Birney  to  Gurley,  Danville,  Ky.,  December  3,  1833. 

141  See  above. 


THE   AMERICAN    COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [488 

risonians  charged  with  hypocrisy,  has  not  yet  been  conclu- 
sively set  forth,  no  more  convincing  documents  could  be 
recommended  to  the  consideration  of  the  investigator  than 
the  lengthy  and  comprehensive  letter  of  Birney,  on  his  sev- 
ering his  connection  with  the  Colonization  movement  to 
become  an  Anti-Slavery  leader,  or  a  similarly  lengthy  and 
comprehensive  letter  of  Gerrit  Smith,  just  a  short  while 
before  he  also  went  over  to  the  Anti-Slavery  party.  Bir- 
ney's  objection  was  not  founded  upon  the  discovery  of  any 
deviation  from  the  straight  line  of  an  altogether  laudable 
policy  to  place  the  free  negro  in  a  position  where  he  would 
not  be  held  down  by  the  shackles  of  prejudice  and,  by  peace- 
able means,  to  bring  about  the  ultimate  and  entire  abolition 
of  slavery,  but  upon  the  belief  that :  "  There  is  not  in  colo- 
nization any  principle,  or  quality,  or  constituent  substance 
fitted  so  to  tell  upon  the  hearts  and  minds  of  men  as  to 
ensure  continued  and  persevering  action."142  And  the  let- 
ter of  Gerrit  Smith  contains  one  of  the  most  exhaustive, 
eloquent,  and  comprehensive  defences  of  the  motives  of  the 
leaders  of  the  Society  that  has  been  presented  to  the  public. 
His  objection  was  not  based  upon  any  discovery  of  the 
slightest  proslavery  designs  or  feelings  among  those  leaders, 
but  upon  the  objection,  in  many  respects  the  very  opposite 
of  that  given  by  Garrisonians,  that  the  Society  had  been 
neglectful  of  the  American  negro  who  was  already  free.148 
It  was  a  great  struggle,  that  between  the  Garrisonians  and 
the  Colonizationists.  Verily,  it  was  the  first  American  civil 
war  on  the  subject  of  slavery.  For  ten  years  it  raged.  The 
outbreak  of  it  was  due  to  Garrison  and  his  confederates  and, 
from  first  to  last,  it  was  a  defensive  contest  from  the  point 
of  view  of  the  Colonization  Society.  When  it  began,  the 
States  were  divided  into  three  comparatively  distinct  sec- 
tions, the  New  England,  the  Middle,  and  the  Southern. 
The  Middle  States  extended  from  New  York  on  the  North 
to  North  Carolina  on  the  South.  There  were  three  pre- 

"2  The  Liberator,  August  16,  1834. 
148  Ibid.,  January  24,  1835. 


489]  COLONIZATION   AND  ABOLITION  177 

vailing  opinions.  In  the  New  England  section,  it  was  the 
Abolition  sentiment,  in  the  Middle  section,  it  was  the  Colo- 
nization sentiment ;  in  the  Southern  section,  it  was  the  posi- 
tive pro-slavery  sentiment.  The  outcome  of  that  struggle 
is  of  deep  significance;  for  when  the  end  of  it  had  come, 
the  middle  section  had  disappeared,  so  far  as  its  importance 
as  a  "buffer  state"  of  public  sentiment  is  concerned. 
Henceforth  there  was  to  be  a  North  and  a  South. 

Striking  evidence  of  this  is  seen  on  the  one  hand  in  the 
fact  that  as  early  as  an  annual  meeting  of  the  Society  in 
1834,  the  delegates  from  Pennsylvania  and  New  York  had 
thrown  many  of  their  former  moderate  views  to  the  winds 
and  were  definitely  antislavery ;  and  on  the  other  hand,  the 
fact  that  the  North  Carolina  Manumission  Society  founded 
in  1816  and,  by  1825,  boasting  of  fifty-eight  auxiliaries  and 
1600  members,  and  the  sympathy  of  probably  a  majority  of 
the  citizens  of  that  State,  founded  with  the  avowed  and 
definite  purpose  of  freeing  North  Carolina  slaves,  held  its 
last  meeting  iii  1834,  and  failed  in  no  small  measure  because 
of  the  revolt  of  North  Carolinians  from  any  thing  that  in 
the  least  savored  of  a  Garrisonian  program.14* 

Under  able  business  management  and  an  efficient  corps  of 
agents  and  advertisers,  Colonization  was  to  continue  to  do 
an  important  work;  but  the  character  of  that  work  had 
changed.  The  struggle  waged  by  the  Abolitionists  had 
made  quite  improbable,  in  the  minds  of  the  mass  of  Ameri- 
cans, the  solution  of  the  negro  problem  by  the  colonization 
plan.  Many  thousands  of  dollars  were  still  to  be  contrib- 
uted ;  but  the  contribution  was  made  rather  as  an  aid  to  the 
establishment  of  a  model  negro  republic  in  Africa,  whose 
effect  would  be  to  discourage  the  slave-trade,  and  encourage 
energy  and  thrift  among  those  free  negroes  from  the  United 
States  who  chose  to  emigrate,  and  to  give  native  Africans 
a  demonstration  of  the  advantages  of  civilization.  In  short, 
the  eyes  of  Colonizationists  were  in  great  measure  turned 
from  a  Southern  slave  system  to  a  Republic  of  Liberia. 

144  University  of  North  Carolina  Magazine,  vol.  xiv,  No.  4,  p.  221. 

12 


178  THE  AMERICAN    COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [490 

Colonization  continued  to  have  a  wide  influence  in  almost 
every  part  of  the  country.  But  it  ceased  to  have  a  con- 
trolling influence  in  any  part  of  the  country.  The  Aboli- 
tionists had  enlisted  those  who  were  to  be  henceforth  pro- 
Northern  advocates ;  and  it  had  definitely  alienated  the  rest 
of  those  who  had  once  been  moderate.  In  a  word,  the  Gar- 
risonians  had  done  much  dangerously  to  divide  the  Union 
into  two  opposing  sections  whose  sentiments  were  in  the 
days  to  come  little  tempered  by  so  moderate  and  unifying 
and  healing  a  sentiment  as  that  held  by  Colonizationists. 
From  the  point  of  view  of  its  influence  upon  the  subject  of 
slavery  Garrison  undoubtedly  won  his  fight,  and  in  doing 
so,  he  was  the  forerunner  and  one  of  the  leading  "  irrepres- 
sible" causes  of  the  "irrepressible"  conflict.  Many  be- 
quests were  yet  to  be  made  to  the  Society,  many  slaves  were 
yet  offered  their  freedom  on  condition  of  emigration,  many 
efforts  were  yet  made  by  those  patriots,  proponents  of  Colo- 
nization, to  hold  the  Union  together,  and  the  Colonization 
Society  lived  on,  doing  a  commendable  work ;  but  the  char- 
acter of  its  work  was  fundamentally  changed  by  the  con- 
flict which  began  in  1831,  and  whose  influence  was  actively 
alive  as  late  as  1845,  though  the  struggle  for  supremacy  may 
be  said  to  have  come  to  an  end. 

By  1842  Garrison  was  calling  the  roll  of  his  ultra- 
Abolitionist  co-workers,  and  he  noted  the  absence  of  most 
of  them.  "  The  time  was/'  said  he,  "  when  Arthur  Tappan 
stood  deservedly  conspicuous  before  the  nation  as  an  aboli- 
tionist, .  .  . ;  but  where  is  he  now  ?  "  "  Where  is  James  G. 
Birney?  In  Western  retiracy,  waiting  to  be  elected  Presi- 
dent of  the  United  States,  that  he  may  have  an  opportunity 
to  do  something  for  the  abolition  of  slavery."  "  Where  is 
Henry  B.  Stanton?  Studying  law,  (which  crushes  human- 
ity, and  is  hostile  to  the  gospel  of  Christ,)  and  indulging  the 
hope  of  one  day  or  other,  by  the  aid  of  the  Liberty  party, 
occupying  a  seat  in  Congress.  .  .  ."  "Where  are  Theo- 
dore D.  Weld  and  his  wife,  and  Sarah  M.  Grimke?" 
"Where  is  Amos  G.  Phelps?  .  .  .  He  is  a  petty  priest,  of 


49 1  ]  COLONIZATION   AND  ABOLITION 

a  petty  parish,  located  in  East  Boston.  What  a  fall!" 
"Where  is  Elizur  Wright,  Jr.,  once  a  flame  of  fire  .  .  .? 
Absorbed  in  selling  some  French  fables  which  he  has  trans- 
lated into  English !  '  Et  tu,  Brute ! ' "  "  Where  is  John  G. 
Whittier?"  "  Where  is  Daniel  Wise  ?"  "  Where  is  Orange 
Scott  .  .  .?  Morally  defunct."  And  so  on,  through  a  list 
of  seventeen  names,  on  all  which  the  African  Repository 
commented :  "  He  could  not  name  ten  others,  who,  in  the 
days  of  his  greatest  success,  were  equally  efficient  in  his 
service."145  What  was  the  trouble  ?  Why  had  these  flames 
gone  out?  Perhaps,  New  Englanders,  the  wisest  of  them, 
were  coming  to  see  the  futility  of  blatant  Garrisonism. 

"'African  Repository,  vol.  xviii,  pp.  327-329. 


CHAPTER  IV 

COLONIZATION  AND  EMANCIPATION,  1817-1850 

A  study  of  the  operations  of  the  American  Colonization 
Society,  if  it  is  to  set  forth  fairly  and  completely  the  Colo- 
nization movement,  must  present  the  efforts  of  that  organi- 
zation from  two  distinct  points  of  view:  (i)  its  effects  and 
results  in  relation  to  the  question  of  slavery,  and  (2)  the 
degree  of  its  success  in  establishing  upon  the  west  coast  of 
Africa  an  asylum  for  the  American  free  negro,  or  the 
American  slave  manumitted  or  emancipated  with  a  view 
to  emigration  to  the  Society's  settlements,  and  for  Africans 
recaptured  from  slave  vessels  and  restored  to  their  native 
land.  In  a  consideration  of  its  bearings  upon  the  solution 
of  the  problem  of  slavery,  no  more  important  topic  can  be 
discussed  than  the  influence  of  the  Society  in  encouraging 
a  spirit  in  the  South  favorable  to  emancipation.  An  accu- 
rate estimate  of  that  influence  is  as  difficult  as  it  is  impor- 
tant. Records  of  emancipations  or  manumissions  are  so 
incomplete  and  unsatisfactory  that  no  summary  can  be 
made  which  will  be  at  once  exhaustive  and  analytical.  If 
every  slaveholder  who  emancipated  his  blacks  told  us 
whether  he  did  so  as  the  result  of  a  distinct  influence  ex- 
erted by  the  Society,  the  problem  would  be  much  simplified. 
But  frequently  the  emancipator  discussed  but  briefly  the 
influences  that  led  to  the  freeing  of  his  slaves.  In  many 
cases  he,  himself,  was  probably  unable  to  analyze  those 
influences.  Perhaps  he  had  been  led  to  give  his  negroes 
their  freedom  because  he  lived  in  a  community  where  eman- 
cipation was  "  in  the  air."  And  perhaps  that  was  the  influ- 
ence of  the  Colonization  Society  at  work.  Influence  cannot 
be  measured  with  a  yard  stick;  and  it  is  exceedingly  diffi- 
cult to  measure  it  at  all. 

180 


493]  COLONIZATION  AND  EMANCIPATION  l8l 

A  further  difficulty  is  found  in  the  fact  that  several  no- 
tices might  appear  in  either  the  official  minutes  or  the  offi- 
cial journal,  the  investigator  being  unable  to  tell  whether 
the  notices  referred  to  are  notices  of  the  same  or  of  different 
cases  of  emancipation.  The  result  is  likely  to  be  a  confu- 
sion of  estimates. 

It  has  already  been  pointed  out1  that,  from  the  hour  of 
its  organization,  indeed,  before  that  hour,  it  was  hoped  that 
one  of  the  important  influences  colonization  might  exert 
would  be  that  in  favor  of  the  gradual  and  entire  abolition 
of  slavery,  through  its  influence  in  favor  of  voluntary  eman- 
cipation. At  an  early  date  William  Thornton  had  already 
expressed  the  desire  and  the  hope  that  it  might  "  afford  the 
best  hope  yet  presented  of  putting  an  end  to  the  slavery  in 
which  not  less  than  600,000  unhappy  negroes  are  now  in- 
volved." He  foresaw  the  day  when  conditions  in  the  South 
would  bring  about  the  enactment  of  laws  prohibiting  eman- 
cipations, unless  accompanied  with  a  provision  for  removal 
from  the  state.2  Before  the  Colonization  Society  was  a 
year  old,  the  Manumission  Society  of  North  Carolina  had 
become  interested  in  cooperating  with  it,  and  after  ten  years' 
observation  of  its  influence  in  favor  of  the  emancipation  of 
slaves,  warmly  recommended  it  and  pledged  its  own  sup- 
port.8 In  a  memorial  presented  to  Congress  in  1819,  a  com- 
mittee, composed  of  two  Virginians,  John  Mason  and  Gen- 
eral Walter  Jones,  one  Marylander,  Francis  Scott  Key,  and 
one  member  from  the  District  of  Columbia,  Dr.  E.  B.  Caldr 
well,  expressed  the  view  that  if  Colonization  resulted  in  the 
complete  abolition  of  slavery,  "Who  can  doubt  that  of  all 
the  blessings  we  may  be  permitted  to  bequeath  to  our  de- 
scendants, this  will  receive  the  richest  tribute  of  their  thanks 
and  veneration."4 

1  See  above. 

2  Thornton  Papers,  MS.,  vol.  xiv,  MSS.  Div.,  Library  of  Cong. 

8  Journal  of  Board  of  Managers  of  American  Colonization  So- 
ciety, MS.,  September  19,  1817;  Manumission  Society  of  North 
Carolina  to  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  September  17,  1827. 

4  Minutes  of  Board  of  Managers  of  American  Colonization  So- 
ciety, MS.,  December  10,  1819. 


1 82  THE  AMERICAN   COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [494 

The  Managers,  in  their  annual  report  in  1820,  declared, 
"  the  hope  of  the  gradual  and  utter  abolition  of  slavery,  in 
a  manner  consistent  with  the  rights,  interests,  and  happiness 
of  society,  ought  never  to  be  abandoned."5  In  their  annual 
report  in  1822,  the  same  body  expressed,  not  only  the  hope, 
but  the  satisfaction,  of  seeing  distinct  evidences  of  the  wil- 
lingness of  slaveholders  to  liberate  their  slaves  for  the  pur- 
pose of  sending  them  to  Africa.6  The  delight  of  those 
Managers  was  expressed  in  still  stronger  terms  in  i823.7 
Lafayette,  for  whom  the  leaders  of  the  Society  had  great 
respect,  and  who  was  one  of  its  vice-presidents,  looked  to 
the  day  when  its  influence  in  bringing  about  emancipation 
would  be  of  great  importance.8  From  the  time  of  its  or- 
ganization to  about  1825,  the  leading  motive  of  those  who 
controlled  the  organization  was  the  elevation  of  the  Ameri- 
can free  negro;  but  the  most  important  secondary  result 
that  they  hoped  the  Society  might  have  was  the  widespread 
cultivation  of  a  sentiment  favorable  to  emancipation.  After 
1825  the  desire  for  the  uplift  of  the  free  negro  and  the 
liberation  of  the  slave  came  to  be  equally  important,  it 
seems,  in  the  policy  of  the  Society.  And  gradually,  and  for 
years  thereafter,  its  efforts  were  directed  more  to  securing 
the  emancipation  of  slaves  than  to  the  elevation  of  the  free 
negro.  It  has  already  been  seen  that  Gerrit  Smith,  in  leav- 
ing the  Society,  made  this  very  criticism  of  it. 

Although  at  no  time  was  the  influence  of  the  Coloniza- 
tionists  exerted  in  opposition  to  emancipation,  it  is  true  that 
during  its  early  years,  the  Society  was  careful  to  violate 
neither  its  own  constitution  nor  local,  municipal  law  on  the 
subject  of  slavery.  For  instance,  there  were  cases  in  which 
runaway  slaves  came  to  the  Society's  agents,  requesting  to 
be  sent  to  Liberia.9  Such  requests  were  refused.  Re- 

5  Origin,   Constitution,  and  Proceedings  of  American  Coloniza- 
tion Society,  MS.,  vol.  i,  p.  107. 

6  Ibid.,  vol.  i,  p.  190. 

7  Ibid.,  vol.  i,  p.  209. 

8  African  Repository,  vol.  i,  p.  285. 

9  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  C.  Wright  to 
Gurley,  Montpelier,  December  29,  1826;  Minutes  of  Board  of  Mana- 


495]  COLONIZATION   AND  EMANCIPATION  183 

quests  were  made  to  the  Society  to  apply  its  funds  directly 
to  the  purchase  of  slaves  for  transportation  to  the  colony. 
These  also  were  refused,  though  agents  of  the  Society  were 
willing  and  glad  to  furnish  lists  of  slaves  who  might  be  pur- 
chased in  order  for  transportation;  and  Gurley  even  went 
so  far  as  to  suggest  that  if  funds  were  placed  in  the  hands 
of  the  Colonization  Society  for  the  express  purpose  of  being 
applied  to  the  benefit  of  those  who,  if  such  funds  were  not 
available,  would  revert  to  slavery,  the  Society  would  gladly 
make  use  of  such  funds  for  the  purpose  designated.10  And 
there  is  on  record  a  case  in  which  twelve  or  fifteen  slaves 
in  Virginia  were  held  in  slavery  for  want  of  funds  to  secure 
their  being  placed  in  the  hands  of  the  Society.  Gerrit 
Smith,  already  turned  Abolitionist,  refused,  it  seems,  to 
furnish  the  financial  assistance,  and  John  McDonogh,  of 
New  Orleans,  a  leader  among  Colonizationists,  directed  the 
treasurer  of  the  Society  to  draw  on  him  for  the  required 
amount.11  When  in  1843  McLain,  Treasurer  of  the  So- 
ciety, was  working  for  the  cause  in  Louisiana,  he  reported 
to  the  Washington  office  that  he  hesitated  to  appeal  for 
funds  because  the  Louisiana  Society  wished  the  first  three 
hundred  dollars  raised  to  be  applied  to  the  purchase  of  "  the 
learned  Blacksmith  of  Alabama,"  a  remarkable  negro  slave. 
This  he  felt  to  be  a  violation  of  the  constitution  of  the 
Society.12 

The  tendency,  however,  never  was  to  construe  too  strictly, 
but  too  liberally,  the  terms  of  the  constitution  in  this  re- 
spect. The  inclination  of  Colonizationists  was  so  favorable 
to  emancipation  that  now  and  then  resolutions  were  sub- 
mitted and  adopted,  whose  object  was  to  remind  the  Society 
that  its  purpose  was,  historically,  to  secure  the  elevation  of 
the  free  negro  rather  than  the  liberation  of  the  slave.  Hon. 

gers  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Sept.  26,  1827;  De- 
cember 12,  1827;  May  19,  1828. 

10  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Gurley  to  Rev. 
H.  J.  Ripley,  December  9,  1842. 

11  Ibid.,  Gurley  to  Ripley,  December  9,  1842,  No.  499. 

12  Ibid.,  McLain  to  Gurley,  New  Orleans,  May  6,  1843;  Finley  to 
Gurley,  Natchez,  May  4,  1843. 


1 84  THE  AMERICAN   COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [496 

Robert  M.  McLane  of  Maryland  secured  in  1849  the  pas- 
sage of  such  resolutions,  which  set  forth  well  the  attitude 
the  Society  took : 

Resolved,  That  in  all  action  affecting  this  institution  [slavery]  in 
its  social  or  political  aspect,  the  American  citizen  and  statesman 
who  reveres  the  Federal  Union  has  imposed  upon  him  the  most 
solemn  obligations  to  respect  in  spirit  and  letter  the  authority  of 
local  and  municipal  sovereignties,  and  to  resist  all  aggressive  influ- 
ences which  tend  to  disturb  the  peace  and  tranquility  of  the  States, 
that  may  have  created  or  sanctioned  this  institution. 

Resolved,  further,  That  the  efforts  of  the  American  Colonization 
Society  to  facilitate  the  ultimate  emancipation  and  restoration  of 
the  black  race  to  social  and  national  independence  are  highly  hon- 
orable and  judicious  and  consistent  with  a  strict  respect  for  the 
rights  and  privileges  of  the  citizens  of  the  several  States  wherein 
the  institution  of  slavery  is  sanctioned  by  municipal  law.18 

Such  reminders  were  needed  especially  for  the  auxiliary 
societies  which,  in  many  instances,  were  with  the  greatest 
difficulty  prevented  from  going  farther  than  was  consistent 
with  the  constitution  in  the  effort  to  liberate  slaves.  No- 
table among  these  was  the  Philadelphia  Society.  Elliot 
Cresson,  for  instance,  wrote  in  1830  that  Philadelphians 
wished  their  funds  used  "  for  the  special  purpose  of  sending 
manumitted  slaves,"  and  suggested  that  free  negroes  be 
required  to  pay  their  own  transportation  expenses.14  Thomas 
Buchanan,  while  agent  for  the  New  York  and  Philadelphia 
Societies,  and  a  short  while  before  his  appointment  as  colo- 
nial governor  of  Liberia,  secured  not  only  the  liberty  of 
forty  slaves  but  also  a  contribution  of  fifteen  hundred  dol- 
lars from  their  owner  to  be  applied  for  their  benefit.15  In 
1843  Treasurer  McLain,  of  the  parent  Society,  was  writing 
to  Virginians  inquiring  for  the  names  of  slaves  whose  lib- 
eration could  be  secured  on  condition  of  their  removal  to 
Africa.  He  thought  he  could  raise  the  money  with  which 
to  secure  the  liberty  of  some  of  them,  though  here  he  was 
undoubtedly  going  beyond  the  constitution  of  the  Society. 
He  wrote:  "We  have  many  friends  who  are  beginning  to 

18  Minutes  of  Board  of  Directors  of  American  Colonization  So- 
ciety, MS.,  January  16,  1849. 

14  Letters   of   American    Colonization   Society,   MS.,    Cresson   to 
Gurley,  Philadelphia,  September  23,  1830. 

15  African  Repository,  vol.  xiv,  p.  54. 


497]  COLONIZATION  AND  EMANCIPATION  185 

feel  a  strong  desire  to  aid  in  sending  slaves  to  Liberia  who 
cannot  be  set  at  liberty  unless  they  are  sent  and  who  cannot 
be  sent  unless  somebody  gives  the  means."16  In  1843  tne 
Massachusetts  Society  was  placing  on  certain  of  its  dona- 
tions the  proviso  that  they  should  be  used  in  defraying  the 
expenses  of  emancipated  slaves."  In  1845  the  Massachu- 
setts agent  wrote :  "  I  think  we  can  get  the  money  for  those 
seven  slaves ;  and  some  of  it  will  be  money  that  we  should 
not  otherwise  receive/'18 

A  peculiarly  interesting  case  is  that  of  the  Kentucky  slave, 
Reuben.  Rev.  J.  B.  Pinney,  agent  for  the  Colonization  So- 
ciety, had  gone  to  Kentucky  to  collect  a  group  of  liberated 
slaves,  twenty-one  of  them,  and  conduct  them  to  the  port 
of  embarkation  for  Liberia.  Among  the  number  was  a 
family  of  children  whose  father  was  still  a  slave.  A  meet- 
ing was  held  in  the  church,  of  which  the  prominent  Colo- 
nizationist,  Dr.  Breckenridge,  was  pastor.  Reuben  was 
asked  if  he  would  like  to  accompany  his  children.  He  ex- 
pressed great  desire  to  go.  The  audience  was  asked  whether 
they  desired  at  once  to  purchase  Reuben  and  send  him  and 
his  children.  Hardly  had  the  invitation  to  contribute  been 
given  when  the  President's  table  was  surrounded  by  those 
who  within  a  few  minutes  had  contributed  a  fund  sufficient 
to  secure  Reuben's  release.19  This  is  interesting  not  alone 
as  an  incident,  but  because  it  throws  a  light  upon  the  atti- 
tude that  a  group  of  Colonizationists  in  a  border  slavehold- 
ing  State  took  toward  the  emancipation  of  a  slave  for  the 
purpose  of  transportation  to  the  colony.  Examples  will 
hereafter  be  given  to  show  that  these  efforts  to  secure  the 
emancipation  of  slaves  were  not  confined  to  the  New  Eng- 
land or  the  Middle  States.  Hundreds  of  slaves  in  Louis- 
iana, Mississippi  and  Tennessee,  as  well  as  in  Kentucky  and 

16  Letters  of  American  Colonization  .Society,  MS.,  McLain  to 
Tracy,  March  7,  1843,  No.  743;  McLain  to  C.  W.  Andrews,  March 
7,  1843,  No.  744- 

r  Ibid.,  Gurley  to  Whittlesey,  Boston,  June  9,  1843. 

18  Ibid.,  Tracy  to  McLain,  Boston,  April  21,  1845. 

19  African  Repository,  vol.  xxi,  pp.  11-12. 


1 86  THE   AMERICAN    COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [498 

Virginia,  were  liberated  because  of  the  efforts  of  Colo- 
nizationists. 

Of  the  effect  of  Colonization  upon  the  spirit  of  emanci- 
pation, considering  the  South  in  general,  President  Thomas 
of  the  Baltimore  and  Ohio  Railroad  wrote,  in  1829:  "... 
the  exertions  of  the  Society  have  already  effected  a  moral 
influence  which  is  obviously  perceptible,"  although  he  real- 
ized that  Colonization  was  only  one  of  the  various  causes 
of  the  change  in  sentiment.20  In  1830  Key  announced  that 
there  were  at  that  time  more  than  six  hundred  slaves  willing 
to  go  to  Liberia  and  offered  by  their  owners  to  the  Society, 
as  soon  as  its  means  were  sufficient  to  care  for  so  many.21 
Benjamin  F.  Butler,  soon  to  be  attorney-general  in  Andrew 
Jackson's  cabinet,  believed  that  the  Colonization  Society 
had  already  "  done  more  to  promote  in  the  Southern  States 
the  Emancipation  of  slaves,  than  had  been  accomplished  by 
all  the  efforts  made  with  direct  reference  to  such  a  result, 
since  the  revolution."  He  stated  that  the  report  of  every 
auxiliary  society  in  the  South  had  testified  to  the  willing- 
ness of  many  slaveholders  to  emancipate  their  negroes  as 
soon  as  they  could  be  transported  and  cared  for  by  the  So- 
ciety.22 William  Maxwell,  a  leading  Colonizationist  of 
Virginia,  bore  witness  to  its  power  as  an  encouragement  to 
slaveholders  to  manumit  their  slaves.23  Elijah  Paine,  of 
Vermont,  expressed  a  similar  view.24  In  the  African  Re- 
pository for  1842,  there  are  notices  of  between  five  and  six 
hundred  slaves  emancipated  for  the  purpose  of  transporta- 
tion to  Liberia,  and  it  must  not  be  forgotten  that  many 
slaveholders  who  were  willing  to  send  their  negroes  to  the 
colony  refused  to  allow  their  names  to  appear  in  the  public 
press.25  In  1845  the  official  journal  of  the  Society  an- 
nounced :  "  Hundreds  of  slaves  have  already  been  set  free 

20  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  P.  E.  Thomas 
to  Gurley,  Baltimore,  September  30,  1829. 

21  African  Repository,  vol.  vi,  pp.  138-139. 

22  Ibid.,  vol.  vi,  p.  162. 

23  Ibid.,  vol.  xiii,  p.  55. 

24  Ibid.,  vol.  xv,  pp.  44-48. 

25  Ibid.,  vol.  xviii,  passim. 


499]  COLONIZATION   AND  EMANCIPATION  l8/ 

in  order  that  they  might  be  removed  to  Liberia.  Hundreds 
more  are  now  offered  to  the  Society,  if  it  will  assume  the 
expense  of  sending  them  out."26 

Of  the  effect  of  the  Society's  influence  in  Kentucky,  the 
general  agent  for  the  West  reported 

a  growing  disposition  for  gratuitous  manumission  and  ...  an 
avowed  determination  on  the  part  of  some  of  our  most  influential 
men  to  press  with  all  their  might  the  subject  of  gradual  abolition 
in  case  a  convention  shall  be  called  to  settle  the  disturbances  of  our 
State,  a  resolution  for  which  has  been  already  introduced  in  the 
House  of  Representatives.  I  mention  this  for  your  private  satis- 
faction ;  I  mean  to  say  its  publication  would  be  premature.  Twenty- 
two  slaves  with  the  means  of  transportation  were  the  other  day 
willed  to  the  Society  by  a  gentleman  in  Bourbon  County  and  eighty- 
odd  have  been  very  recently  liberated  by  one  man  in  Clarksville, 
Tennessee.  I  would  mention  several  other  cases  of  which  I  have 
been  particularly  informed.27 

Again,  in  1829,  he  wrote  that  many  slaveholders  were  ready 
to  liberate  their  slaves  when  they  could  be  received  by  the 
Society.28  A  member  of  the  Kentucky-  State  Society  called 
attention  to  the  very  widespread  sentiment  in  favor  of 
emancipation,  and  attributed  it,  in  considerable  measure,  to 
the  influence  of  the  Colonizationists,  though  he  admitted 
that  an  effort  had  been  made  to  drag  it  into  politics,  the 
Jackson  men  saying  "it  is  a  party  thing."29  R.  J.  Breck- 
enridge,  while  yet  a  resident  of  Kentucky,  declared  in  1831 : 

IMs  now  generally  admitted,  that  a  very  large  number  of  those 
owning  slaves,  perhaps  as  many  as  one-third  of  them,  would  decid- 
edly favor  the  gradual  emancipation  of  the  slaves  of  this  State; 
provided  the  great  accumulation  of  free  negroes  supposed  to  be  con- 
sequent on  such  a  step  could  be  avoided.  Among  the  non-slave- 
holders, I  never  saw  a  person  of  ordinary  intelligence,  who  was  not 
decidedly  favorable  to  some  efficient  project  of  that  sort. 

One  of  the  secrets  of  the  Society's  influence  throughout 
the  upper  South  was  that  it  proposed  not  only  to  emanci- 
pate, but  also  to  remove;  and  it  must  never  be  forgotten 
that  one  of  the  most  powerful  objections  to  the  abolition  of 

26  Ibid.,  vol.  xxi,  pp.  145-149;  vol.  xix,  p.  189;  vol.  xx,  p.  229; 
Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Mary  B.  Blackford 
to  Gurley,  Fredericksburg,  Va.,  January  28,  1843. 

27  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  B.  O.  Peers  to 
Gurley,  Maysville,  Ky.,  December  n,  1826. 

1  Ibid.,  Peers  to  Gurley,  Feb.  7,  1829. 
29  Ibid.,  Gurley,  Lexington,  Ky.,  September  5,  1828. 


1 88  THE  AMERICAN   COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [500 

slavery,  from  the  point  of  view  of  the  South,  was  that  the 
free  negro  would  become  a  black  peril  to  the  South.80 

Robert  S.  Finley,  a  son  of  the  venerable  Robert  Finley, 
assured  the  parent  Society  that  it  could  secure  without  diffi- 
culty all  the  emigrants  it  could  accommodate.  "I  have 
heard,"  he  wrote,  "  within  the  last  ten  days  without  making 
particular  inquiries  on  the  subject  of  hundreds  of  slaves 
who  are  only  held  in  bondage  until  the  Colonization  Society 
will  undertake  to  colonize  them.  And  I  have  no  hesitation 
in  saying  that  there  are  thousands  of  slaves  in  this  State 
who  are  merely  held  by  their  masters  in  trust  for  the  same 
praiseworthy  object.'*31  In  1839,  an  assistant  secretary  of 
the  Society  wrote  as  hopefully  as  had  Finley.32  Elliot 
Cresson,  traveling  in  the  interest  of  the  Society,  wrote  from 
Mississippi  in  1840  that  the  whole  South,  and  particularly 
Kentucky,  seemed  to  be  ready  to  cooperate  in  the  coloniza- 
tion of  its  slaves.33 

In  Virginia  there  were  not  wanting  signs  of  the  Society's 
influence.  The  State  Colonization  Society  and  the  Lynch- 
burg  Society  reported  large  numbers  of  slaves,  as  well  as 
free  negroes,  desiring  to  go  to  the  colony,  many  of  the 
slaves  being  offered  their  liberty  on  condition  of  removal 
by  the  Society.84  Monroe  once  told  Elliot  Cresson  that  if 
the  Society  could  raise  funds  sufficient  to  care  for  the  set- 
tlers, he  could  procure  ten  thousand  slaves  by  emancipation 
in  Virginia  alone.86 

In  North  Carolina  as  late  as  1840,  the  Society's  agent 
reported  continued  growth  of  sentiment  favorable  to  eman- 
cipation if  accompanied  by  removal.  One  slaveholder,  the 

80  African  Repository,  vol.  vii,  pp.  48-49. 

81  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  R.  S.  Finley  to 
Gurley,  Lexington,  Ky.,  April  12,  1831. 

82  Ibid.,  Knight  to  Wilkeson,  Frankfort,  Ky.,  November  30,  1839. 
88  Ibid.,  Cresson  to  Wilkeson,  Natchez,  Miss.,  April  13,  1840. 

84  African  Repository,  vol.  iv,  pp.  307-311;  vol.  y,  p.  203;  vol.  vi, 
pp.  214-215 ;  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Atkin- 
son to  Gurley,  Petersburg,  Va.,  December  17,  1831. 

85  African  Repository,  vol.  xv,  p.  84;  Letters  of  American  Coloni- 
zation Society,  MS.,  Gurley  to  Rev.  Stephen  Taylor,  July  13,  1842, 
No.  148. 


5Ol]  COLONIZATION   AND  EMANCIPATION  189 

owner  of  upwards  of  one  thousand  negroes,  was  reported 
as  determined  to  emancipate  them  all  if  the  colony  con- 
tinued to  improve  and  if  the  Society  could  make  provision 
for  them.38  So  efficient  were  the  North  Carolina  Quakers 
in  their  cooperation  with  the  Society,  that  they  alone  seemed 
able  to  supply  all  the  emigrants  that  could  be  accommodated 
with  the  limited  means  of  the  Colonizationists.  From  1825 
to  1830,  slaveholders  in  that  State  placed  in  the  hands  of 
these  Quakers  hundreds  of  slaves,  on  condition  of  their  re- 
moval to  Liberia.87 

It  must  not  be  supposed  that  there  were  no  counter  influ- 
ences. In  comparing  the  Abolition  and  Colonization  move- 
ments it  has  already  been  set  forth  that  one  of  the  strongest 
of  these  counter  forces  was  the  Abolitionists  themselves. 
Whether  by  picturing  in  dark  colors  the  motives  of  Coloni- 
zationists, or  by  assuring  the  negroes  that  emigration  was 
not  their  privilege,  but  rather  their  banishment,  or  by  pic- 
turing the  terrors  of  the  sea  or  the  ferocity  of  the  native 
Africans  or  the  fatal  consequences  of  the  period  of  acclima- 
tion in  the  colony,  or  the  fact  that  the  negro  had  a  right  to 
enjoy  the  same  privileges  in  America  that  his  white  brother 
had,  or  by  speaking  of  slaveholders,  and  to  slaveholders,  in 
terms  calculated  to  exasperate  not  only  an  enemy  but  a 
friend — in  all  these  ways,  and  more,  the  Garrisonians  were 
working  up  a  sentiment  which  made  it  impossible  for  the 
Northern  States  and  the  Southern  to  meet  on  common 
ground  in  the  solution  of  a  great  problem. 

It  is  a  fact,  and  a  fact  altogether  neglected  by  proponents 
of  Garrison,  that  no  considerable  section  of  American  citi- 
zenship would  have  borne  Garrisonian  insult  without  uniting 
in  opposition.  His  own  New  England  would  have  risen  in 
as  radical  opposition,  as  it  did  rise  in  radical  support,  if  he 
had  spoken  of  its  citizenship  in  the  same  unmeasured  terms 

86  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  W.  McKenney 
to  Wilkeson,  Greensboro,  N.  C,  Nov.  6,  1840. 

"Ibid.,  J.  C.  Ehringhaus  to  Gurley,  Elizabeth  City,  N.  C.,  Sep- 
tember 30,  1826;  Cresson  to  Gurley,  Aug.  23,  1828;  African  Reposi- 
tory, vol.  v,  p.  94. 


THE  AMERICAN    COLONIZATION    SOCIETY  [$O2 

that  he  used  in  describing  Southerners.  This  is  true  be- 
cause a  man's  a  man,  and  not  a  superman.  Too  much  has 
been  made  of  the  peculiarities  of  Southern  temperament 
and  not  enough  made  of  the  peculiarities  of  Garrisonian 
abuse.  Garrison  thought  of  the  South  in  terms  of  Ephraim 
and  his  Idol,  and  that  was  true  in  1831  of  a  part  of  the 
lower  South.  But  a  truer  picture  of  the  upper  South  in 
1831  would  have  been  that  represented  by  Prometheus 
Bound. 

Garrison's  abuse  furnished  the  South  with  the  best  justi- 
fication it  ever  had  for  plunging  into  civil  war.  Ultra- 
Abolition  made  a  patriot  of  many  a  man  who  could  not  have 
fought  with  great  earnestness  to  preserve  the  institution  of 
slavery.  Garrisonian  methods  made  patriots  of  Southern 
opponents  of  slavery,  for  they  enabled  the  South  to  stand, 
not  only  as  the  defender  of  a  bad  thing  but  also  as  the  de- 
fender of  a  good  thing;  not  only  as  a  defender  of  slavery, 
but  also  of  the  Constitution  of  the  United  States.  Coloni- 
zationists  took  away  the  strongest  ground  the  South  had  to 
stand  on  in  her  defense  of  slavery,  for  Colonizationists  ad- 
mitted that  the  Constitution  stood  between  them  and  the 
positively  proslavery  advocates.  Garrisonians,  by  refusing 
fully  to  admit  that,  had  a  large  part  in  the  very  making  of 
their  arch-enemy  Calhoun.  They  gave  him  the  opportunity 
of  defending  the  South  in  the  same  breath  with  which  he 
defended  the  Constitution.  They  assisted  him  powerfully 
in  making  his  reputation  as  a  great  political  theorist,  as  well 
as  a  great  proslavery  advocate.  It  may  now  appear  that 
radical  abolitionism  was  pregnant  not  only  with  influences 
opposed  to  Colonization,  but  also  with  influences  opposed  to 
emancipation. 

Other  counter  influences  should  be  mentioned,  such  as  the 
injudicious  publication  of  articles  advocating  emancipation, 
the  belief  of  some  slaveholders  that  their  "people"  would 
not  be  safe  in  the  colony  from  the  dangers  of  hostile  tribes 
and  that  proper  provision  was  not  made  for  receiving  them, 
the  fear  that  their  slaves  after  being  liberated  might  escape 


503]  COLONIZATION   AND  EMANCIPATION 

from  the  vessel  before  it  left  port,  the  unwillingness  of  many 
negroes  to  go  to  Liberia,  the  refusal  of  some  slaveholders 
to  encounter  public  criticism,  the  extreme  sensitiveness  of 
portions  of  the  South,  and  particularly  of  Virginia,  to  any 
efforts  made  to  secure  aid  from  the  Federal  Government, 
and  the  widespread  realization  that  already  the  Coloniza- 
tionists  had  more  applicants  than  their  funds  would  permit 
of  sending  to  Africa.38 

Indeed,  there  was  probably  not  a  time  during  the  whole 
period  herein  considered  when,  notwithstanding  the  counter 
influences  of  which  mention  has  just  been  made,  the  Society 
could  not  have  enlarged  greatly  its  operations  and  secured 
the  liberation  of  a  much  larger  number  of  slaves  than  were 
given  over  to  it,  if  it  had  had  funds  sufficient  to  settle  them. 
As  early  as  1827  the  Managers  were  compelled  to  refuse 
passage  to  recently  emancipated  slaves  in  parts  of  Virginia, 
and  of  slaves  who  would  be  emancipated  to  go  to  the  col- 
ony.89 The  public  journal  of  the  Society  contains  many 
evidences  that  Abolitionists  could  have  secured  at  once  the 
liberation  of  hundreds  and  thousands  of  slaves  if  they  had 
been  willing  to  contribute  to  the  support  of  the  Society 
which  could  get  slaves  for  the  asking  when  Garrison  could 
not  have  bought  them  at  any  price. 

The  panic  of  1837  was  very  disastrous  to  the  enlarging 
opportunities  of  the  Society.  John  McDonogh  of  Louis- 
iana thought  that  in  1840  there  were  hardly  fifty  solvent 
men  in  New  Orleans,40  and  that  same  year  the  treasurer  of 
the  Society  was  appealing  to  friends  in  the  North  to  furnish 
the  means  without  which  the  liberty  of  certain  slaves  could 

88  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Hunt  to  Gur- 
ley,  Brunswick,  Va.,  October  5,  1826;  Brand  to  Gurley,  Richmond, 
Va.,  August  20,  1827;  Brand  to  Gurley,  Richmond,  Va.,  November 
3,  1827;  M.  B.  Blackford  to  Gurley,  Fredericksburg,  Va.,  August 
18,  1845 ;  McLain  to  Rev.  N.  S.  Dodge,  February  20,  1843,  No.  677 ; 
W.  M.  Blackford  to  Gurley,  Fredericksburg,  Va.,  October  21,  1829; 
C.  S.  Carter  to  Gurley,  Richmond,  Va.,  December  22,  1831 ;  African 
Repository,  vol.  xii,  p.  89;  vol.  xiv,  pp.  43-47. 

80  Minutes  of  Board  of  Managers  of  American  Colonization  So- 
ciety, MS.,  March  26,  1827. 

40  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Cresson  to 
Wilkeson,  New  Orleans,  April  2,  1840. 


192  THE  AMERICAN   COLONIZATION  SOCIETY  [504 

not  be  secured.  "  We  are  trying  hard,"  wrote  McLain,  "  to 
raise  the  means  of  sending  to  Liberia  about  40  liberated 
slaves,  who  must  be  sold  again  into  slavery  if  not  sent  soon. 
In  these  circumstances  we  should  be  unfaithful  to  the  im- 
portant trusts  committed  to  us,  if  we  did  not  appeal  to  every 
friend  of  the  colored  man  for  help."41  Letters  were  sent 
to  leading  Colonizationists  throughout  the  United  States  for 
aid  in  securing  the  liberty  and  transportation  of  slaves 
offered  for  the  Colony. 

In  1841  the  general  agent,  Judge  Wilkeson,  thus  instructed 
McLain  who  was  working  for  the  cause  in  the  South: 
"Study  economy  and  take  the  negro  only  who  will  go  to 
slavery  unless  sent  to  Liberia,  unless  his  expenses  are 
paid."42  Appeals  were  made  during  this  year  to  save  from 
slavery  and  the  cupidity  of  heirs  eleven  slaves  in  Kentucky, 
and  at  another  time,  eighteen  slaves  from  the  same  State.48 
The  appeal  of  the  Colonizationists  was:  "We  must  save 
them";  "What  shall  we  do?  We  have  now  no  means  of 
defraying  their  expenses.  Let  them  be  sold?  We  never 
could  justify  this  to  the  American  people."  "More  emi- 
grants offer  than  we  can  raise  the  means  of  sending."  In 
1842  a  slaveholder  of  Nashville,  Tennessee,  desired  to  place 
in  the  hands  of  the  Society  for  emigration  sixty  slaves;  a 
slaveholder  living  near  New  Orleans  made  an  offer  of 
eighty  slaves ;  a  lady  in  Virginia  desired  to  make  the  same 
disposition  of  some  sixty  of  her  "people,"  but  the  Society 
had  not  the  funds  to  fit  out  an  expedition.4* 

During  that  year  the  treasurer  sent  to  a  slaveholder  the 
following  refusal:  "I  wish  it  was  in  my  power  to  inform 
you  that  the  Soc.  could  pay  the  expenses  of  sending  the 
family  you  wish  to  liberate.  But  the  applications  are  so 
numerous  and  the  Soc.  so  in  debt,  the  Ex.  Committee  have 

41  Ibid.,  McLain  to  Hubbard,  December  30,  1840,  No.  487 ;  Presi- 
dent Humphrey  of  Amherst,  December  30,  1840,  No.  490. 

42  Ibid.,  Wilkeson  to  McLain,  April  6,  1841,  No.  114. 

48  Ibid.,  McLain  to  D.  Baldwin,  vol.  iv,  No.  1542;  Theodore  Fre- 
linghuysen,  August  26,  1841,  No.  70. 

44  Ibid.,  Gurley  to  Jacob  Gibson,  February  14,  1842,  No.  629;  Gur- 
ley  to  George  Barker,  February  17,  1842,  No.  641. 


505]  COLONIZATION  AND  EMANCIPATION  193 

been  obliged  to  resolve  that  for  the  present  they  can  send 
out  none  but  such  as  can  pay  their  own  expenses."45  And 
within  about  three  months  he  was  appealing  for  $7500.00 
with  which  to  fit  out  an  expedition,  on  which  one  hundred 
and  sixty-seven  slaves  were  to  go  to  Liberia  "if  we  can 
send  them,"  otherwise  a  part  of  them  were  to  revert  to 
slavery.  "Oh,  that  our  Northern  friends  but  understood 
the  magnitude  and  importance  of  the  great  work  in  which 
we  are  engaged."46  But  appeals  to  New  England  failed  of 
the  desired  results.  Mr.  Garrison  had  declared  that  it  was 
the  purpose  of  the  Colonizationists  to  "  rivet  more  firmly 
the  fetters  of  the  slave." 

To  those  who  suppose  that  the  only  reason  slaveholders 
could  offer  for  continuing  to  hold  their  slaves  was  that  they 
preferred  to  do  so,  it  may  be  of  value  to  point  out  some  of 
the  problems  involved  in  the  liberation  by  a  master  of  his 
negroes;  and  to  show  that  there  were  slaveowners  in  the 
South  who  despised  the  institution  and  who  were  glad  of 
an  opportunity  to  be  rid  of  the  responsibility  and  burden 
when  they  found  an  opportunity  to  do  so  with  safety,  as 
they  thought,  to  their  country.  In  1827  a  Mississippi  slave- 
holder, preparing  his  twenty-three  negroes  for  emigration 
to  Liberia,  wrote  the  Society,  telling  of  the  farming  tools 
and  carpenter's  outfit  he  hoped  to  give  them  on  their  depar- 
ture, and  thus  expressed  his  gratification  at  finding  a  way 
out  of  the  burden  of  slaveholding : 

I  hope  that  it  will  be  in  the  power  of  the  Society  to  give  them  a 
passage  early  in  June,  that  I  may  be  enabled  to  wipe  from  my  char- 
acter the  foulest  stain  with  which  it  was  ever  tarnished  and  pluck 
from  my  bleeding  conscience  the  most  pungent  sting.  I  had  fully 
determined  several  years  past  to  emancipate  them  about  this  time 
but  had  been  much  perplexed  in  my  mind  in  relation  to  their  future 
place  of  residence,  until  I  learned  that  Heaven  had  provided  an 
asylum  in  the  land  of  their  ancestors,  where  I  had  long  been  of 
opinion  it  was  right  that  they  should  be  transported  and  with  them 
the  seeds  of  civilization  and  Christianity  to  make  some  amends  .  .  . 
for  the  many  wrongs  and  outrages  committed  ...  by  a  people  who 
styled  themselves  Christians  for  so  many  centuries.47 

45  Ibid.,  McLain  to  Dr.  W.  S.  Holcombe,  August  17,  1842,  No.  236. 

46  Ibid.,  McLain  to  G.  W.  Campbell,  November  29,  1842,  No.  445; 
Gurley  to  Dr.  A.  Proudfit,  No.  448;  Gurley,  No.  336. 

47  Ibid.,  Silas  Hamilton  to  Gurley,  Adams  County,  Miss.,  Decem- 
ber 28,  1827. 

13 


194  THE  AMERICAN    COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [506 

Sometimes  the  difficulty  was  in  the  expense  involved  in  the 
preparation  of  the  slaves  for  liberty,  and  one  would  be  sur- 
prised to  read  the  many  evidences  of  real  desire  on  the  part 
of  those  masters  who  offered  their  slaves  to  the  Society  to 
send  their  negroes  well  prepared,  well  equipped,  and  well 
provisioned.48  William  Johnson,  of  Western  Virginia,  who 
was  the  owner  of  nine  slaves,  one  of  whom  he  had  bought 
with  the  express  purpose  of  freeing  him  with  his  sister,  was 
an  uneducated,  poor,  but  sincere  slaveholder  for  conscience 
sake.  After  making  two  attempts  "  to  try  to  git  money  to 
send  them  to  liberia,"  he  appeals  to  the  Society  to  relieve 
him  of  the  burden.49 

In  many  cases  the  difficulty  was  simply  one  of  deciding  what 
to  do  with  the  slaves  if  they  were  to  be  freed.  It  has  been 
seen  that  in  most  of  the  Southern  States  the  laws  against 
emancipations  within  the  State  were  made  more  stringent 
and  were  more  strictly  enforced  after  the  Garrisonian  onset 
and  the  development  of  the  cotton  industry.  The  result 
was  that  slaveholders,  no  matter  what  they  thought  of  the 
evils  of  slavery,  could  not  lawfully  manumit,  except  by 
transporting  the  manumitted  to  some  part  of  the  Union,  or 
to  some  other  place  where  such  prohibitory  laws  were  not 
in  operation.  Sometimes,  it  seems,  the  very  consideration 
of  the  advantages  of  the  Colonization  movement  led  directly 
and  immediately  to  the  determination  to  emancipate,  on 
condition  of  removal.50  Sometimes  the  difficulty  arose 
from  the  unwillingness  to  divide  families,  separating  hus- 
hand  and  wife,  parents  and  children,  one  of  the  most  repul- 
sive aspects  of  the  whole  repulsive  system  of  slavery. 

It  would  not  be  practicable  in  a  study  of  this  nature  to 
attempt  a  complete  summary  of  even  the  most  interesting 
instances  of  emancipation  and  transportation  to  the  colony ; 
but  it  is  important  to  mention  a  number  of  such  cases.  A 

1  Ibid.,  A.  M.  Marbury  to  Gurley,  Alexandria,  Va.,  May  26,  1835. 

49  Ibid.,  Wm.  Johnson  to  Fendall,  Tyler  County,  Va.,  November 
26,  1836. 

50  Ibid.,  McKenney,  Norfolk,  Va.,  December  27,  1832 ;  C.  W.  An- 
drews to  Gurley,  Richmond,  Va.,  February  I,  1836;  C.  C.  Harper, 
Baltimore,  Md.,  April  24,  1828. 


507]  COLONIZATION   AND  EMANCIPATION  195 

flood  of  light  is  thereby  thrown  upon  the  inquiries:  What 
portion  of  the  South  furnished  the  largest  number  of  eman- 
cipations to  the  Society?  What  portion  furnished  the 
largest  number  of  large  single  emancipations?  What  pro- 
visions were  made  for  the  emancipated  slaves  ?  What  con- 
ditions were  attached  to  the  acts  of  emancipation?  Did 
those  who  sent  portions  of  their  slaves  to  the  colony  ex- 
press, after  hearing  from  them,  a  willingness  to  send  others  ? 
Were  those  emancipated  chiefly  the  old  and  infirm,  or  were 
the  emigrants  able-bodied,  valuable  negroes?  Up  to  and 
including  1832,  among  the  emancipations  with  provision  for 
emigration  to  Liberia,  are  the  following : 

A  lady  from  near  Charles  Town,  Virginia,  liberated  ten 
slaves ;  also  two  slaves  whom  she  purchased  because  of  their 
relation  to  her  own.  For  these  two  she  gave  $800.  They 
were  manumitted  for  the  purpose  of  emigration  to  Africa.61 
William  H.  Fitzhugh,  a  Vice-President  and  active  member 
of  the  Colonization  Society,  by  will  liberated  all  his  slaves, 
numbering  about  three  hundred.  Their  liberation  was  to 
date  from  1850.  Upon  their  consent  to  go  to  Liberia,  and 
they  were  to  have  their  freedom  whether  or  not  they  agreed 
to  go  to  the  Colony,  their  passage  was  to  be  paid  and  they 
were  to  be  given  fifty  dollars  each.52 

David  Shriver,  of  Maryland,  by  will  emancipated  his 
thirty  slaves;  Colonel  Smith,  of  Sussex  County,  Virginia, 
by  will  emancipated  seventy  or  eighty,  leaving  about  $5000 
for  their  transportation  and  settlement.53  Miss  Patsy  Morris, 
of  Virginia,  by  will  emancipated  her  sixteen  slaves,  leaving 
$500  for  their  passage  to  the  colony.  Sampson  David,  of 
Tennessee,  emancipated,  by  will,  his  twenty-two  slaves,  and 
Herbert  B.  Elder,  of  Petersburg,  Virginia,  twenty.  A 
Georgian  liberated  forty-nine,  the  greater  part  of  his  for- 
tune, on  condition  that  they  should  go  to  the  colony.  In 

81  Carey,  pp.  8-9. 

82  Minutes  of  Board  of  Directors  of  American  Colonization  So- 
ciety, MS.,  January  j8,  1849,  P-  74- 

88  Carey,  pp.  8-9;  African  Repository,  vol.  ii,  pp.  29-30. 


196  THE  AMERICAN   COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [508 

North  Carolina  alone  there  had  been  offered  to  the  Society 
six  hundred  and  fifty-two  slaves.54 

Mrs.  Elizabeth  Moore,  of  Kentucky,  provided,  by  will, 
for  the  emancipation  of  all  her  slaves,  about  forty.  Charles 
Henshaw,  of  Virginia,  manumitted  sixty  to  send  them  to 
Liberia.55  A  Mr.  Funston,  of  Frederick  County,  Virginia, 
emancipated  ten  slaves,  and  by  will  provided  $1000  to  cover 
their  transportation  expenses.69  Another  Virginia  slave- 
holder emancipated  one  hundred  and  ten  slaves.  Another, 
a  Methodist  minister  of  Suffolk,  Virginia,  emancipated  up- 
wards of  thirty,  leaving  several  hundred  dollars  to  be  ap- 
plied to  their  transportation.67  A  Virginia  lady  emanci- 
pated twenty-five,  and  a  slaveholder  of  Kentucky,  sixty.58 
David  Bullock,  of  Virginia,  emancipated  twenty-three,  the 
oldest  not  over  forty  years.  This  slaveholder  inquires  for 
the  negroes  as  to  "their  expectations  when  they  arrive,  as 
to  their  immediate  support,  and  their  future  chance  for  liv- 
ing, whether  they  will  have  land  allotted  to  them,  etc."59 
Among  those  emancipated  after  1832,  are  the  following: 

The  New  Orleans  Picayune  contains  this  announcement : 
"We  understand  that  six  hundred  negroes,  belonging  to  a 
gentleman  of  this  city,  lately  deceased,  are  to  be  liberated 
according  to  his  will,  provided  they  are  willing  to  go  to 
Africa,  in  which  case  ample  provision  is  to  be  made  for 
their  transportation."60  Another  slaveholder  was  willing 
to  emancipate  sixty,  if  funds  could  be  secured  with  which 
to  transport  them  to  the  colony.61  John  McDonogh,  of 
New  Orleans,  was  ready  in  1842  to  send  eighty  or  eighty- 
five  slaves,  valued  at  $150,000.00,  well  trained  and  an  un- 
usual acquisition.  Of  McDonogh's  negroes,  about  fifty-five 

64  Carey,  pp.  8-9 ;  African  Repository,  vol.  ii,  p.  163 ;  vol.  iv,  p.  185. 

65  African  Repository,  vol.  i,  pp.  191-192. 

66  Ibid.,  vol.  ii,  pp.  352-353- 

67  Ibid.,  vol.  iii,  p.  27. 

58  African  Repository,  vol.  iv,  p.  251. 

69  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  D.  Bullock  to 
Gurley,  Louisa,  Va.,  September  13,  1827. 

60  African  Repository,  vol.  xiv,  p.  63,  copied  from  New  Orleans 
Picayune,  February  13,  1838. 

81  African  Repository,  vol.  xviii,  p.  80. 


509]  COLONIZATION   AND  EMANCIPATION 

were  adult  and  the  rest  children  from  six  to  twelve  years 
of  age.  So  far  was  the  colonization  mode  of  securing  the 
emancipation  of  slaves  favorably  looked  upon,  even  in 
Louisiana,  that  a  New  Orleans  paper  commented  in  the 
most  favorable  terms  upon  both  the  Society,  Mr.  Mc- 
Donogh,  and  his  philanthropic  scheme  of  emancipating  all 
his  negroes,  and  upon  the  condition  of  the  colony  as  re- 
vealed in  the  letters  sent  back  to  persons  in  the  State  from 
the  negroes  he  had  sent  out.  These  letters  abounded  in 
expressions  of  thankfulness  and  gratitude  to  their  former 
master  for  his  generosity  and  liberal  treatment  of  them. 

McDonogh  had  worked  out  a  plan  by  which  the  negroes 
were  allowed  to  earn  their  own  freedom,  by  using  advan- 
tageously certain  hours  and  days  given  them  for  that  pur- 
pose by  their  master.  It  was  one  of  the  most  interesting 
plans  ever  proposed  for  the  liberation  of  slaves  without 
actual  expense  to  the  owner.  McDonogh  found  that,  if  the 
slave  used  well  the  time  given  to  him,  he  could  secure  his 
own  freedom  within  fifteen  or  seventeen  years.  This  free- 
dom he  gave  to  those  who  were  his  own  property.  And 
although  The  Liberator  and  other  Abolitionist  papers  se- 
verely criticised  the  plan,  McDonogh  was  trying  to  recom- 
mend to  the  southern  slaveholder  a  plan  by  which  he  could 
rid  his  country  of  slavery  and  at  the  same  time  do  so  with- 
out great  loss  to  himself.62 

In  1832  Major  Bibb,  of  Kentucky,  sent  thirty-two  of  his 
slaves  to  the  colony,  and  the  following  year  he  tendered 
freedom  to  the  remaining  forty,  on  condition  that  they 
would  emigrate.63  This  year  also,  Dr.  James  Bradley,  of 
Georgia,  manumitted  about  sixty  negroes,  who  emigrated  to 
the  Colony.6*  The  following  year  Dr.  T.  M.  Ambler,  of 
Virginia,  emancipated  about  thirty,  who  went  to  the  Col- 

62  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  McLain,  New 
Orleans,  La.,  July  2,  1844;  Gurley  to  Proudfit,  March  7,  1842,  No. 
677;  African  Repository,  vol.  xix,  p.  48  ff. ;  pp.  141-142. 

68  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  G.  C.  Light  to 
Gurley,  Cynthiana,  Ky.,  June  6,  1833. 

64  Lugenbeel. 


198  THE  AMERICAN   COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [Sl° 

ony.65  In  1834  Dr.  John  Ker,  one  of  the  most  prominent 
Colonizationists  in  the  Southwest,  wrote  asking  that  sixteen 
of  a  considerable  number  of  slaves  left  free,  on  condition 
of  their  emigration,  by  James  Green  of  Mississippi,  be  al- 
lowed passage : 

I  am  authorized  to  say  that  they  [the  executors]  will  pay  the  whole 
expense  of  their  emigration,  and,  agreeably  to  the  will  of  the  Testa- 
tor, will  furnish  them  with  a  very  handsome  outfit,  amounting,  for 
those  over  twelve  years  old,  to  from  three  to  five  hundred  dollars, 
and  somewhat  less  for  the  younger  ones.  .  .  .  You  will  allow  me  to 
bespeak  for  them  ...  all  the  attention  and  favor  which  may  be 
necessary  to  their  comfortable  and  eligible  establishment  in  the 
Colony.66 

In  1836  Gurley  visited  Mississippi  in  the  interest  of  the 
Society,  and  his  report  to  the  Managers  throws  an  interest- 
ing light  upon  the  attitude  of  that  State  toward  emancipa- 
tion, and  also  upon  the  estate  of  the  deceased  James  Green, 
and  the  purpose  of  the  principal  executor  in  relation  to  the 
remaining  slaves.  Gurley  was  forcibly  impressed  with  the 
liberality  and  cordiality  of  the  Colonizationists  of  that  State. 
They  had  contributed  two  thousand  dollars  "without  my 
personal  application  to  a  single  individual,  and  with  my 
detention  hardly  for  a  day." 

On  Monday,  I  visited  James  Railey,  Esq.  (principal  executor  of 
the  estate  of  the  late  James  Green)  at  his  beautiful  country  seat. 
...  Its  generous  proprietor  opened  to  me  fully  his  mind  in  regard 
to  the  estate  .  .  .  with  written  and  verbal  requests  that  it  should  be 
applied  to  the  emancipation  and  colonization  of  slaves  front  Missis- 
sippi in  Liberia.  It  will  be  recollected,  that  certain  slaves  emanci- 
pated by  Mr.  Green  have  been  sent  to  the  colony,  and  Mr.  Railey 
informs  me,  that  their  outfit  and  supplies  and  passage  cost  about 
$7000.  The  trust  might,  in  the  opinion  of  some,  be  fulfilled,  were 
$20000  in  addition,  applied  to  the  benevolent  purposes  of  the  testa- 
tor, but  Mr.  Railey  states  that  it  has  been  determined  to  devote 
$25000  more  to  the  objects  of  testator's  charitable  desires.67 

Alexander  Donelson  of  Tennessee  died  in  1834,  emanci- 
pating his  slaves  by  will.  By  the  laws  of  the  State,  negroes 
freed  within  its  bounds  were  compelled  to  leave  or  revert 
to  slavery,  unless  they  were  by  the  county  court  permitted 

••  Ibid. 

66  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Ker  to  Gurley, 
Natchez,  Miss.,  January  10,  1834. 

67  Ibid.,  Gurley  to  Fendall,  June  30,  1836. 


5  III  COLONIZATION   AND  EMANCIPATION  199 

to  remain.  By  decree  of  that  court,  Donelson's  slaves  were 
allowed  to  remain  in  the  State  until  the  time  of  embarka- 
tion, if  they  agreed  to  start  for  Liberia  by  January  20,  1836. 
The  slaves  were  twenty  in  number.  All  were  grown,  and 
none  over  forty  years  of  age.  Donelson  had  left  them  all 
his  personal  property,  amounting  to  a  considerable  sum. 
They  had  ample  means  to  provide  themselves  with  clothes, 
tools,  and  provisions.  They  could  pay  their  own  passage 
and  still  have  money  left  after  arriving  in  the  colony.  The 
son  of  the  deceased  had,  by  careful  management,  increased 
considerably  the  fund  left  by  Donelson.  He  had  left  them 
together  on  the  farm,  had  allowed  them  to  continue  their 
work,  and  had  given  them  the  proceeds  of  the  crop.68  In 
1834  one  hundred  and  nine  slaves  owned  by  Dr.  Hawes,  of 
Virginia,  were  liberated  and  transported  to  the  Colony.69 

A  Colonizationist  from  Hanover  County,  Virginia,  wrote 
the  Society  in  1836  that  a  family  of  thirty  slaves  had  been 
liberated  in  that  county,  on  condition  of  their  emigrating 
to  the  colony.  Their  passage  was  to  be  paid,  and  a  sum 
sufficient  for  their  comfortable  settlement  was  to  be  given 
them.  Another  family,  twenty-seven  in  number,  had  been 
liberated  in  the  adjoining  county.  To  each  of  the  twenty- 
seven  a  legacy  of  one  hundred  and  fifty  dollars  was  left  for 
the  purpose  of  enabling  them  to  settle  either  in  some  free 
State  or  in  some  country  where  they  might  enjoy  their  lib- 
erty. They  had  apparently  decided  to  go  to  Liberia.70 
During  this  year  also,  forty-two  slaves,  liberated  by  Wil- 
liam Foster,  of  Mississippi,  arrived  in  the  colony.71  In 
1837  Thomas  Potts,  of  Virginia,  emancipated  and  sent  to 
the  colony  fifty-nine  negroes,  paying  the  expense  of  their 
passage,  amounting  to  four  thousand  and  fifty  dollars.72 

68  Ibid.,  T.  H.  Fletcher  to  Gurley,  Nashville,  Tenn.,  August  12, 

1835- 

69  Lugenbeel. 

70  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  N.  C.  Cren- 
shaw  to  Fendall,  Hanover  County,  Va.,  July  15,  1836. 

71  Sketch  of  the  History  of  Liberia,  MS. 

72  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Potts  to  Fen- 
dall, Sussex  Court  House,  Va.,  October  13,  1837;  November  18, 
1837. 


2OO  THE  AMERICAN   COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [512 

In  1840  an  agent  of  the  Society  for  Kentucky  wrote :  "  A 
gentleman  in  this  vicinity  tendered  me  twenty  slaves  lately 
for  emigration,  upon  condition  that  they  were  willing  to  go, 
and  we  would  provide  them  means."78  The  year  preceding 
this,  John  Rix,  of  North  Carolina,  sent  twenty  slaves  lib- 
erated by  him  to  Liberia.  John  McPhail,  whose  efforts  for 
the  Society  in  preparing  for  the  sailing  from  Norfolk  of  a 
number  of  expeditions  were  of  the  greatest  value,  reported 
in  1839  that : 

I  expect  a  family  of  fifteen  probably  the  forerunner  of  a  large 
number  belonging  to  [a  certain  gentleman],  if  he  should  agree  to  the 
terms  you  may  propose  to  take  them  out  and  provide  for  them  six 
months  after  their  arrival  in  Africa.  .  .  .  This  is  an  affair  I  believe 
of  much  importance  to  the  interest  of  the  Society.  I  do  not  exactly 
know  how  many  the  gentleman  owns  but  I  am  certain  they  amount 
to  some  hundreds;  if  he  makes  his  mind  up  upon  the  subject  he  will 
send  by  every  expedition  some  families.  He  writes  to  me  in  perfect 
confidence  and  says,  "  I  wish  nothing  said  of  it  either  privately  or 
publicly  and  no  notice  of  it  in  the  newspapers.  .  .  ."7* 

In  1842  Wm.  B.  Lynch,  of  Virginia,  emancipated  nine- 
teen slaves  on  condition  of  their  willingness  to  go  to  Africa. 
For  their  passage  he  appropriated  five  hundred  dollars.75 

In  1844  Lieut.  C.  W.  Tomkins  offered  for  his  sister  to 
liberate  about  forty  slaves  if  they  would  go  to  Liberia.  The 
same  year  Mrs.  Jane  Meaux,  of  Kentucky,  left,  by  will, 
liberty  to  fourteen  slaves  on  condition  that  they  would  go 
to  the  colony.  Each  was  to  be  given  one  hundred  dollars 
upon  agreement  to  go,  besides  being  furnished  with  house- 
hold and  kitchen  furniture.  Of  these  slaves,  the  oldest 
was  about  thirty-five.76 

Colonel  Montgomery  Bell  of  Tennessee  sent  companies 
of  manumitted  slaves  to  the  colony  at  various  times.  By 
1854,  he  had  already  sent  eighty-eight,  and  it  was  his  pur- 
pose to  continue  until  the  whole  number,  some  two  hundred 

™  Ibid.,  Henkle  to  Wilkeson,  Louisville,  Ky.,  May  5,  1840. 

74  Ibid.,  volume  of  omitted  letters,  1839-1842,  John  McPhail  to 
Wilkeson,  Norfolk,  Va.,  November  16,  1839. 

75  Ibid.,  W.  B.  Lynch  to  McLain,  Lynchburg,  Va.,  November  7, 
1842. 

78  Ibid.,  Tomkins  to  McLain,  Beaufort,  N.  C,  September  i,  1844; 
T.  E.  West  to  McLain,  NicholasYille,  Ky.,  December  7,  1844. 


513]  COLONIZATION   AND  EMANCIPATION  2OI 

and  fifty  had  been  transported.77  Colonel  Bell's  slaves  were 
very  valuable.  For  a  single  one  of  them  he  had  refused 
five  thousand  dollars,  which  was  offered  a  short  while  be- 
fore the  negro  embarked  for  the  colony.  Bell  was  merely 
waiting  until  the  funds  of  the  Society  were  sufficient  to 
send  the  rest  of  the  people.78 

It  will  already  have  been  observed  that  many  acts  of 
emancipation  were  incorporated  in  the  wills  of  slavehold- 
ers. This  was  a  favorite  method  of  offering  liberty  to  the 
slaves.  The  act  of  emancipation,  no  matter  when  effected, 
involved  a  radical  readjustment  of  the  affairs  of  an  estate, 
and  must  have  had  much  to  do  with  the  choice  of  this 
method.  It  may  be  well  to  consider  some  notable  cases  of 
slaves  left  free  by  will,  in  addition  to  those  already  noted. 
It  will  here  appear  that  on  a  number  of  occasions  the  So- 
ciety sued  for  the  liberty  of  slaves.  In  jnany  cases  where 
suits  were  not  instituted  the  liberty  of  the  slaves  was  se- 
cured, or  the  possibility  of  their  being  set  free  investigated, 
by  agents  of  the  Society.79  Sometimes  they  forestalled 
threatened  or  actual  attempts  to  violate  the  provisions  of 
emancipations  contained  in  wills.80 

By  the  will  of  Dr.  Bradley  of  Virginia  in  1831,  all  his 
negroes,  numbering  about  fifty,  were  to  be  allowed  to  emi- 
grate to  the  colony.  Their  expenses  were  to  be  paid  out  of 
the  proceeds  of  the  estate.  Those  who  were  unwilling  to 
go  were  to  revert  to  slavery.81  They  were  of  all  ages,  from 
infants  to  sixty  years.  In  1835  application  was  made  for 
passage  to  Liberia  for  forty-four  slaves  left  free  by  the  will 
of  Thomas  Hickenbotham,  of  Virginia.  Most  of  them 
were  in  the  prime  of  life.82  The  same  year,  General  Black- 

77  Journal  of  Executive  Committee  of  American  Colonization  So- 
ciety, MS.,  June  23,  1854. 

78  Ibid.,  January  16,  1854 ;  December  30,  1854. 

79  Minutes  of  Board  of  Managers  of  American  Colonization  So- 
ciety, MS.,  August  30,  1825 ;  April  24,  1826. 

80  Ibid.,  October  22,  1827. 

81  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  R.  Jordan  to 
Gurley,  Monticello,  Va.,  February  26,  1831. 

82  Ibid.,  C.  H.  Page  to  Gurley,  New  Glasgow,  Va.,  June  4,  1835. 


2O2  THE  AMERICAN    COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [514 

burn,  also  of  Virginia,  emancipated  by  will  his  forty-six 
slaves  on  condition  of  their  willingness  to  go  to  the  colony ; 
the  expense  of  their  transportation  to  be  paid  out  of  the 
proceeds  of  the  estate.88 

One  of  the  most  interesting  bequests  of  slaves  to  the  So- 
ciety was  that  of  Captain  Ross,  of  Mississippi.  In  1834, 
Ross  made  a  will  bequeathing  to  his  granddaughter  a  woman 
servant,  Grace,  with  all  her  children,  unless  Grace  should 
elect  to  go  to  Liberia,  in  which  case  she  and  her  children 
were  to  be  conveyed  thither.  The  granddaughter  was  de- 
sired to  maintain  comfortably  the  testator's  man  servant, 
Hannibal  and  his  sisters,  Daphne,  Dinah,  and  Rebecca. 
Hannibal  was  to  receive  an  annuity  of  one  hundred  dollars, 
and  each  of  his  sisters  an  annuity  of  fifty  dollars.  In  case 
they  should  elect  to  go  to  Liberia,  there  was  to  be  given,  in 
place  of  the  annuities,  to  Hannibal  five  hundred  dollars. 
Enoch,  his  wife  Merilla,  and  their  children  were  to  be  sent 
to  some  free  State  where  they  could  be  legally  manumitted. 
To  Enoch  was  to  be  given  also  five  hundred  dollars,  unless 
he  and  his  family  should  elect  to  go  to  Africa,  in  which  case 
they  should  be  conveyed  thither,  five  hundred  dollars  being 
paid  him  upon  his  departure. 

The  rest  of  his  slaves  and  property  were  to  be  left  to 
Ross'  daughter,  Mrs.  Margaret  Reed,  for  the  rest  of  her 
natural  life,  or  until  she  was  disposed  to  carry  out  the  re- 
maining provisions  of  his  will,  in  relation  to  slaves  and 
property.  Upon  Mrs.  Reed's  death,  or  her  decision  to  carry 
out  her  father's  design,  all  of  the  slaves  of  the  age  of 
twenty-one  years  and  upwards,  save  those  above  referred 
to,  and  five  others  whose  names  were  given,  were  to  be 
assembled  by  the  executors,  who  were  to  explain  to  them 
the  provisions  of  the  will  and  invite  them  to  determine 
whether  or  not  they  desired  to  go  to  Liberia.  Those  who 
desired  to  go  were  to  be  conveyed  thither,  and  those  refus- 
ing to  go  were  to  be  sold  at  auction,  with  the  restriction  that 
families  were  not  to  be  separated.  The  proceeds  from  the 

88  Ibid.,  J.  H.  Peyton  to  Laurie,  Staunton,  Va.,  August  8,  1835. 


515]  COLONIZATION   AND  EMANCIPATION  2C>3 

sale  and  any  other  funds  belonging  to  the  testator's  estate 
were,  after  the  payment  of  expenses,  to  be  paid  into  the 
treasury  of  the  Colonization  Society,  to  be  applied  to  the 
transportation  and  maintenance  of  the  slaves  who  elected 
to  go.  The  total  number  of  the  slaves,  when  the  will  was 
made,  was  about  one  hundred  and  seventy. 

Ross  was  a  planter  of  excellent  judgment.  The  returns 
from  the  estate  were  large.  But  the  Captain,  it  seems, 
applied  its  great  revenues  to  the  comfort  of  his  "people." 
It  was  estimated  that  the  estate  brought  in  a  revenue  of 
some  $20,000  a  year.  Of  the  slaves,  Gurley  wrote :  "  His 
slaves  were  kept  disconnected  from  those  on  other  planta- 
tions, and  therefore  constituted  one  great  family  of  one 
hundred  and  seventy  in  number,  who  have  been  treated 
more  like  children  than  slaves.  For  industry,  intelligence, 
and  good  order,  none  are  their  superiors.  To  render  them 
happy  appears  to  have  been  the  great  object  of  their  mas- 
ter." Dr.  John  Ker,  whose  name  appears  so  often  in  any 
study  of  the  Colonization  movement  in  Mississippi,  said  of 
Ross:  "His  slaves  .  .  .  felt,  in  a  high  degree,  the  mutual 
attachment  which  is  not  uncommon  in  the  South  between 
master  and  slave,  and  which  ought  to  put  to  shame  the  slan- 
ders of  ignorant  or  wicked  Northern  fanatics.  He  ardently 
desired  to  provide  for  their  welfare  and  happiness  after  his 
death." 

Ross  died  in  1836,  and  his  daughter  made  a  will  which 
was  intended  to  carry  out  exactly  the  wishes  of  her  deceased 
father.  By  1840,  however,  the  provisions  of  the  will  were 
being  earnestly  contested  by  certain  of  the  heirs.  The  latter 
were  able  to  arouse  sentiment  in  their  favor  throughout  the 
State,  and  the  fight  was  carried  into  the  State  Legislature 
in  1841  or  1842,  where  the  result  was  the  passage  of  a  bill 
in  the  lower  house,  by  which  it  would  have  been  made  un- 
lawful for  the  slaves  to  be  emancipated  even  on  condition 
of  their  removal  to  the  colony.  The  High  Court  of  Errors 
and  Appeals  had  already  decided  favorably  to  the  validity  of 
the  will,  and  the  attempt  of  the  legislature  was  in  reality  an 


204  THE  AMERICAN   COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [5*6 

attempt  to  annul  an  already  announced  decision  of  that  court. 

Dr.  Ker  just  at  this  time  rendered  the  Colonization  So- 
ciety the  valuable  service  of  opposing  with  great  energy  the 
passage  of  the  bill  when  it  came  up  for  consideration  in  the 
Senate,  of  which  he  was  a  member.  By  a  campaign  of  pub- 
licity and  by  great  exertion  he  blocked  this  move  to  hold  the 
slaves  in  slavery.  The  value  of  the  estate  in  1840,  was 
estimated  to  be  about  $200,000,  and  it  was  to  be  used  for 
provisioning  the  Ross  and  Reed  slaves  in  Liberia  and  in 
providing  educational  institutions  in  the  colony.  In  1842 
the  total  number  of  slaves  who  were  intended  to  be  benefited 
by  the  will  was  upwards  of  three  hundred.  It  appears  that, 
after  years  of  effort  and  vigilance,  the  Society  won  its  point 
and  secured  the  liberty  of  the  slaves.  Let  those  who  doubt 
the  sincerity  of  Gurley,  John  Ker,  Captain  Ross,  or  Rev. 
Zebulun  Butler,  during  the  days  when  the  Colonization 
scheme  was  assailed  by  Garrisonians  as  a  hypocritical  collu- 
sion with  the  friends  of  perpetual  slavery,  consule  refer- 
ences here  given  bearing  upon  the  efforts  both  in  and  out  of 
the  courts  to  establish  the  Ross  and  Reed  wills.84 

Another  interesting  example  is  that  of  Richard  Tubman 
of  Georgia.  The  law  of  Georgia  did  not  permit  the  eman- 
cipation of  slaves  within  the  State;  but  Tubman  tried  to 
secure  a  special  act  of  permission  by  making  provision 
for  a  liberal  legacy  to  several  of  the  literary  institutions  of 
the  State,  if  the  permission  to  emancipate  were  granted. 
The  legislature  refused  the  request.  Application  was  made 
to  the  Society  to  transport  the  slaves,  except  four  old  men 
whose  mistress  had  consented  at  their  request  to  keep  them. 
Of  the  remaining  forty-four  none  was  over  forty  years  of 
age.  The  widow  of  the  deceased  paid  the  negroes,  the  year 
after  her  husband's  death,  $1000  for  the  crop  they  had 

**  African  Repository,  vol  xii,  pp.  233-235 ;  vol.  xv,  pp.  3-4 ;  vol. 
xvi,  p.  50 ;  vol.  xviiij  p.  99  ff.  Letters  of  American  Colonization  So- 
ciety, MS.,  Gurley  to  Fendall,  Rodney,  Miss.,  July  22,  1836;  Z.  But- 
ler to  McLain,  Port  Gibson,  January  10,  1844;  Gurley  to  McLain, 
New  York,  July  22,  1845;  Gurley  to  Butler,  September  29,  1843, 
No.  228. 


517]  COLONIZATION   AND  EMANCIPATION  2O$ 

raised.  The  value  of  the  slaves  was  estimated  at  not  less 
than  $4O,ooo.85 

In  1837  application  was  made  for  the  transportation  of 
thirty-five  slaves  belonging  to  William  Hunton  who,  by  will, 
had  offered  them  their  freedom  on  condition  that  they  would 
go  to  the  colony.  Otherwise  they  were  to  revent  to  slav- 
ery.86 In  1840  William  Smart,  of  Virginia,  left,  by  will, 
between  twenty  and  thirty,  all  of  his  negroes,  on  condition 
that  they  should  go  to  the  colony.87  During  this  same  year, 
there  were  two  other  cases  of  emancipations  in  Virginia 
that  should  here  be  noted :  James  Fox  liberated  about  fifty 
negroes  on  condition  that  they  should  go  to  Liberia,  other- 
wise they  were  to  revert  to  slavery;88  and  Mrs.  Carter 
offered  freedom  to  twenty-six  on  condition  that  they  should 
go  to  the  colony.89  In  Kentucky  John  Graham  by  will  pro- 
vided that  after  1850  his  slaves,  fifteen  in  number,  were  to 
have  their  liberty  on  condition  of  their  willingness  to  emi- 
grate to  the  colony.90  In  1842  Thomas  Wallace,  deceased, 
left  by  will  fourteen  slaves  free  on  the  condition  of  their 
going  to  the  colony.81 

Secretary  McLain  of  the  Society  wrote  to  one  of  the 
Colonization  agents  in  December,  1842 :  "  Keep  in  mind  the 
old  gentleman  near  Nashville,  Tennessee,  who  wants  to  lib- 
erate his  68  slaves  before  he  dies  to  keep  them  out  of  the 
hands  of  his  only  heir  who  is  opposed  to  their  liberation. 
The  Old  man  is  in  feeble  health — he  is  poor  and  cannot  de- 
fray their  expenses.  About  $3000  will  carry  them  to  the 
colony  and  support  them  six  months."92  In  1843  Thomas 
Lindsay,  of  Missouri,  emancipated  by  will  twenty-one  slaves 

85  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Wm.  Y.  Allen 
to  Gurley,  Augusta,  Ga.,  December  29,  1836. 

86  Ibid.,  John  Marr  to  Mercer,  Warrenton,  Va.,  October  23,  1837. 

88  Ibid.,  Brand  to  Wilkeson,  Richmond,  Va.,  August  18,  1840. 

89  Ibid.,  M.  B.  Blackford  to  Wilkeson,  Fredericksburg,  Va.,  Sep- 
tember 1 6,  1840. 

90  Ibid.,  F.  M.  Bristow  to  Wilkeson,  Elkton,  Ky.,  November  24, 
1840. 

91  Ibid.,  L.  W.  Andey,  Flemingsburg,  Ky.,  September,  1842. 

92  Ibid.,  McLain  to  Dodge,  December  27,  1842,  No.  516;  McLain 
to  Dodge,  October  27,  1842,  No.  342. 


2O6  THE  AMERICAN   COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [518 

on  condition  of  their  emigration  to  Liberia ;  and  in  Virginia, 
Hardenia  M.  Burnley  emancipated  by  will  the  same  num- 
ber, their  transportation,  outfit,  clothing  and  maintenance 
in  the  colony  for  six  months  being  provided  for  out  of  the 
estate.98 

One  of  the  most  interesting  cases  of  emancipation  by  will 
was  that  of  Mr.  Hooe  of  Virginia  in  1845.  Hooe  provided 
for  the  emancipation  of  his  two  hundred  slaves  in  Virginia 
and  one  hundred  and  fifty-eight  in  Mississippi  and  Alabama. 
Property  sufficient  to  provide  for  their  transportation  was 
left  to  the  Society,  and  the  supervision  of  the  execution  of 
the  will  was  placed  directly  in  Gurley's  hands  as  an  execu- 
tor. Gurley's  comment  was:  "...  so  much  depends  on 
examples  like  that  of  Mr.  Hooe  as  to  the  prospect  of  future 
emancipations,  that  special  efforts  should  be  made  that  the 
humane  purpose  contemplated  may  be  fully  realized." 
There  was  considerable  probability  that  that  portion  of  the 
will  directing  the  emancipation  of  those  slaves  who  were  in 
Mississippi  and  Alabama  would  be  contested.  Gurley  ad- 
vised as  to  these,  "  to  ascertain,  as  fully  as  possible,  whether 
it  is  possible  to  institute  any  process,  by  which  their  case 
can  be  brought  before  the  courts  of  the  United  States.  .  .  . 
The  executors  are  solemnly  bound  to  neglect  no  possible 
legal  means  of  securing  the  freedom  of  those  slaves,  and  for 
one,  I  wish  any  measure,  even  if  unpromising,  adopted."94 

By  will  of  Stephen  Henderson  of  Louisiana,  his  slaves, 
five  or  six  hundred  in  number,  were  to  be  emancipated  for 
the  purpose  of  emigration  to  the  colony.  The  first  ten, 
chosen  by  lot,  were  to  go  within  five  years  after  Hender- 
son's death ;  after  ten  years,  twenty  more  were  to  go ;  and 
after  twenty-five  years  the  remainder.  The  will  was  con- 
tested but  was  upheld  by  the  Supreme  Court  of  Louisiana.95 

98  Ibid.,  G.  C.  Sibley  to  Gurley,  Linden-Wood,  Missouri,  July  15, 
1843;  J-  O.  St'eger  to  McLain,  Richmond,  Va.,  December  n,  1843. 

94  Ibid.,  Wm.  Coppinger  to  McLain,  Philadelphia,  Pa.,  July  22. 
1845;  Gurley  to  McLain,  New  York,  August  12,  1845,  October  28, 
1845. 

9«  New  Orleans  Commercial  Bulletin,  August  15,  1845. 


519]  COLONIZATION   AND  EMANCIPATION  2O/ 

Besides  these  acts  of  emancipation  of  slaves  for  the 
colony  and  these  bequests  of  money  and  of  slaves,  the  rec- 
ords of  the  Society  contain  many  interesting  letters  of  in- 
quiry. Many  slaveholders  offered  the  Society  their  slaves 
when  it  would  be  ready  to  take  them.  Many  others  wrote 
for  advice  as  to  the  disposition  of  the  slaves,  advice  which 
Garrisonians  were  denied  the  privilege  of  giving.  The  real 
sacrifice  some  slaveholders  were  willing  to  make  for  the 
sake  of  emancipating  their  slaves  it  set  forth  in  these  letters. 
The  care  with  which  they  prepare  the  slave  for  the  time 
when  he  must  depend  upon  his  own  efforts  is  also  evident. 
In  short,  the  Society  was  a  sort  of  clearing  house  where  the 
views  of  moderate  Southerners  and  moderate  Northerners 
were  exchanged,  and  where  the  spirit  of  emancipation 
worked  silently  but  mightily.  Several  examples  of  letters 
of  this  character  will  suffice. 

Rev.  Thomas  P.  Hunt  of  Richmond,  Virginia,  desired  to 
emancipate  his  twenty  slaves,  but  was  unable  to  provide 
funds  sufficient  for  their  transportation.  He  proposed  that 
he  be  accredited  as  an  agent  in  order  to  secure  the  funds 
necessary  for  their  transportation  to  the  colony.96  Mrs. 
Barbie  of  Kentucky  was  perplexed  as  to  the  disposition  of 
five  or  six  slaves  which  she  had  not  yet  inherited,  but  which 
were  to  fall  to  her.  She  hoped  they  might  be  transported 
to  the  colony  as  soon  after  they  came  into  her  possession  as 
possible.97  A  South  Carolinian  wrote  for  advice  as  to  the 
disposition  of  his  negroes,  twenty-five  in  number.  The  act 
of  emancipation  would  leave  him  a  bare  competency  the 
rest  of  his  life  and  he  was  consequently  unable  to  bear  the 
expense  of  transportation.98 

A  typical  inquiry  was  that  sent  from  Fincastle,  Virginia, 
in  1832 :  "  I  have  from  fifteen  to  twenty  negroes  I  wish  to 
emancipate.  Will  your  Society  receive  and  transport  them 

96  Minutes  of  Board  of  Managers  of  American  Colonization  So- 
ciety, MS.,  August  14,  1826. 

97  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  J.  C.  Crane  to 
Gurley,  Richmond,  Va.,  October  26,  1826. 

98  Ibid.,  W.  H.  Robbins,  Cheraw,  S.  C,  October  12,  1827. 


2O8  THE  AMERICAN    COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [$20 

to  Liberia?"  or:  "I  have  for  a  considerable  time  past  de- 
termined to  emancipate  my  slaves  if  such  facilities  would 
be  afforded  them  (by  the  Society  of  which  you  are  Agent) 
in  getting  off  to  the  colony  of  Liberia,  as  are  necessary  and 
proper  for  their  accommodation."99  The  slaves  are  valued 
at  $3500.00.  A  Colonizationist  from  Lynchburg,  Virginia, 
'reported  four  groups  of  slaves  held  ready  for  manumission 
whenever  the  first  opportunity  offered  to  send  them  to 
Liberia.100 

A  citizen  of  Missouri  desired  to  emancipate  four  slaves, 
three  of  whom  he  bought  for  the  express  purpose  of  eman- 
cipating them  as  soon  as  they  had  refunded  to  him,  in  labor, 
the  amount  expended  in  their  purchase.  Already  he  had 
executed  to  them  deeds  of  emancipation  on  condition  of 
their  willingness  to  go  to  the  colony.101  A  South  Caro- 
linian offered  his  thirteen  negroes  to  the  Society  to  be  taken 
to  Liberia.  "  He  has  long  had  it  in  his  heart  to  do  this ;  but 
he  has  not  known  in  what  way  to  effect  it,  and  has  requested 
me  to  open  a  correspondence  with  the  Society.  .  .  .  Neither 
the  old  man  nor  his  wife  can  die  in  peace  without  doing  all 
they  can  to  place  their  servants  in  a  condition  where  they 
may.  enjoy  liberty."  The  Society  was  to  be  given  three 
hundred  dollars  toward  the  cost  of  transportation,  and  each 
negro  man  was  to  have  one  hundred  dollars  and  each 
woman  fifty  dollars.102 

In  1843  William  B.  Lynch,  of  Virginia,  sent  off  his  eighteen 
slaves  for  Liberia.  Lynch  had  proposed  to  take  them  to 
the  Northwestern  States  to  enjoy  their  liberty;  but  after  a 
visit  of  inquiry,  he  concluded  that  to  enjoy  an  equal  oppor- 
tunity and  real  freedom,  they  must  be  removed  to  the  col- 
ony. Upon  their  leaving  for  Liberia  he  paid  five  hundred 

99  Ibid.,  G.  Terrill  to  Gurley,  Fincastle,  Va.,  September  10,  1832; 
T.  L.  Leftwich,  Liberty,  Va.,  Sept.  14,  1832. 

100  Ibid.,  W.  M.  Rives,  Lynchburg  Va.,  October  16,  1832. 

101  Ibid.,  John  Conway  to  Gurley,  Bonhomme,  Mo.,  November  25, 
1837- 

102  Ibid.,  B.  Gildersleeve  to  Gurley,  Charleston,  S.  C,  April  7, 
1841 


52 1]  COLONIZATION   AND  EMANCIPATION 

dollars  towards  the  cost  of  transportation.103  One  of  those 
choice  Colonization  spirits  among  the  women  of  Virginia 
was  Mrs.  Mary  B.  Blackford.  She  had  prepared  Abram 
to  be  sent  to  the  colony,  and  her  care  for  him  is  of  interest : 

Giving  him  his  freedom  and  outfit  is  as  much  as  I  can  do  being 
limited  in  my  funds.  My  brother  writes  me  he  is  very  apt  in  learn- 
ing any  trade  he  is  put  to  and  suggests  his  being  put  to  learn  the 
carpenter's  trade  before  he  goes,  but,  I  fear  if  I  kept  him  here  for 
the  purpose,  something  would  occur  to  prevent  his  having  his  free- 
dom. ...  my  heart  is  greatly  set  on  this  plan.  .  .  .  Pray  ask  that 
he  may  be  cared  for  during  the  fever;  if  he  were  to  die  I  should 
feel  a  heavy  responsibility  on  me.10* 

Joseph  H.  Wilson  of  Kentucky  was  anxious  that  his 
twenty-seven  slaves  should  have  a  passage  to  Liberia.  They 
were  valued  at  $12,000;  and  besides  emancipating  them,  he 
proposed  to  give  them  $1000  or  $1200.  The  Society's  agent 
thus  commented  upon  Wilson's  treatment  of  his  negroes: 
"  He  has  no  children  and  makes  his  slaves  the  object  of  his 
kindness.  .  .  .  the  only  evil  I  can  see  is  that  when  they 
set  up  for  themselves,  as  free  people,  .  .  .  they  will  feel 
the  loss  of  the  care  of  their  present  owners,"  for  he  here 
referred  also  to  two  other  families  of  slaves  whose  masters 
desired  to  emancipate  them.105  Mrs.  Mary  B.  Blackford, 
writing  in  behalf  of  a  friend  who  desired  to  emancipate  and 
send  to  the  colony  her  six  slaves,  commented  on  the  particu- 
lar case : 

She  will  do  her  utmost  in  sending  these  people  away,  or  rather  in 
giving  them  their  freedom,  and  I  know  it  is  entirely  out  of  her 
power  to  furnish  them  with  necessary  funds.  If  some  who  judge 
slaveholders  so  hardly,  knew  all  that  I  do  of  the  conscientiousness, 
generous  self-denial,  insurmountable  obstacles,  which  they  would  so 
gladly  do  away  with,  how  differently  they  would  regard  them.  In 
Virginia  the  owner  is  almost  as  much  to  be  pitied  as  the  slave.108 

108  African  Repository,  vol.  xix,  p.  201. 

104  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  M.  B.  Black- 
ford  to  Gurley,  Fredericksburg,  Va.,  September  2,  1843. 

105  Ibid.,  Pinney  to  McLain,  Bardsville,  June  10,  1844. 

108  Ibid.,  M.  B.  Blackford  to  McLain,  Mt.  Airy,  Va.,  February  2, 
1845;  J.  W.  Norwood  to  Gurley,  Hillsborough,  N.  C,  1826;  Miss 
Judith  Blackburn  to  Gurley,  Mount- Vernon,  March  29,  1831 ;  J.  L. 
Crawford  to  Gurley,  Danville,  Ky.,  February  27,  1842;  G.  W.  Mc- 
Phail  to  McLain,  Fredericksburg,  Va.,  November  n,  1845;  African 
Repository,  vol.  vii,  pp.  271-272. 


21O  THE  AMERICAN    COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [$22 

It  will  be  noted  that  no  references  have  been  made  to 
slaves  offered  from  Maryland,  although  that  State  was  one 
of  the  first  in  the  number  offered  for  settlement  in  Africa. 
It  will  be  remembered  that  very  early  in  the  thirties  the 
Maryland  Society  assumed  an  independent  attitude  toward 
the  parent  Society.  Thereafter  the  slaves  offered  were 
offered  directly  to  the  State  organization,  and  no  record 
therefore  appears  on  the  official  documents  of  the  Society.107 

When  an  expedition  was  preparing  to  leave  New  Orleans 
the  latter  part  of  the  year  1848,  there  were  four  hundred 
and  seventy-nine  negroes  who  had  applied  for  passage  to 
the  colony.  Of  these,  two  hundred  were  those  from  the 
Ross  estate,  to  revert  to  slavery  if  they  were  not  removed 
by  the  end  of  January.108 

The  problem  was  not  the  difficulty  in  securing  the  eman- 
cipation of  slaves  or  the  want  of  inclination  to  encourage 
emancipation,  but  the  want  of  funds  to  carry  out  their 
benevolent  designs.  If  the  Society  had  had  the  means  it 
could  have  secured  thousands  more  of  the  slaves  of  the 
South  and  could  have  made  them  freemen;  and  those  who 
measure  the  work  and  influence  of  that  organization  by  the 
actual  number  of  slaves  transported  have  gotten  a  very  in- 
adequate conception  of  its  influence  or  its  usefulness.  The 
need  of  funds  in  the  sending  out  of  the  expedition  just 
spoken  of  is  but  one  of  many  examples  that  might  be  pre- 
sented to  show  the  inability,  for  want  of  funds,  to  meet  its 
opportunities.  If  the  States  north  of  Mason  and  Dixon's 
line  had  offered  as  much  money  in  cash  as  the  States  south 
of  that  line  offered  in  slaves,  leaving  out  of  account  the 
many  thousands  of  dollars  contributed  in  cash  to  the  treas- 
ury of  the  Society  from  the  slaveholding  States  themselves, 

m  For  reports  of  expeditions  sent  out  to  the  colony,  see  Minutes 
of  Board  of  Managers  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Feb- 
ruary 9,  1829 ;  Journal  of  Executive  Committee  of  American  Coloni- 
zation Society,  MS.,  November  28,  1848;  March  15,  1851;  April  19, 
1851;  November  7,  1851;  December  16,  1852;  November  18,  1853; 
January  16,  1854;  December  20,  1854;  etc. 

108  Journal  of  Executive  Committee  of  American  Colonization 
Society,  MS.,  November  28,  1848. 


523]  COLONIZATION   AND   EMANCIPATION  211 

the  statistics  of  emancipations  would  be  written  in  quite  dif- 
ferent figures.  Or  if  the  influence  of  the  Society  were  even 
measured  by  the  number  of  slaves  offered  to  it,  rather  than 
by  the  limited  number  it  was  able  to  transport,  those  figures 
would  still  require  a  radical  revision. 

But  taking  the  figures  as  they  are :  by  1830  over  two  hun- 
dred of  the  slaves  freed  and  sent  out  to  Liberia  had  been 
emancipated  by  their  masters  for  the  express  purpose  of 
emigration  to  the  colony.109  In  1841  Gurley  wrote  that  the 
Society  "has  secured  the  voluntary  manumission  of  slaves, 
(about  2000)  in  value  (viewed  as  property)  nearly,  if  not 
quite,  equal  to  the  whole  amount  of  funds  given  for  the 
establishment  of  Liberia ;  while  its  influence  to  prepare  for 
future  emancipations  it  were  difficult  to  estimate."110  Judge 
Wilkeson  estimated  the  proportion  of  emancipated  slaves  to 
free  negroes  taken  to  the  colony  as  more  than  one  for  one.111 
By  the  beginning  of  1855,  about  3600  slaves  had  been  actu- 
ally emancipated  with  a  view  to  their  settlement  in  Li- 
beria.112 By  the  time  the  Society  was  fifty  years  old  (1867) 
the  number  of  slaves  actually  emancipated  and  sent  to  the 
colony  was  about  6ooo.113 

109  A   Few   Fact's,  published   by  American   Colonization   Society, 
MS.,  1830. 

110  27th  Cong.,  3d  sess.,  H.  Rept.  No.  283,  p.  1023. 

111  Minutes  of  Board  of  Directors  of  American  Colonization  So- 
ciety, MS.,  July  20,  1841. 

112  Ibid.,  January  16,  1855. 

113  Half-Century  Memorial,  American  Colonization  Society,  1867. 


212 


THE  AMERICAN    COLONIZATION   SOCIETY 


[524 


A  LIST  OF  SLAVES  EMANCIPATED  OR  OFFERED  FOR  EMANCIPATION  FOR 
EMIGRATION  TO  LIBERIAN  COLONY,  1825-1835,  INCLUSIVE. 

The  list  given  below  must  not  be  taken  as  official.  _  It  is  a  compi- 
lation collected  from  various  sources.  Doubtless  it  is  very  incom- 
plete. It  will  be  of  value,  however,  as  showing  the  distribution  of 
offered  emancipations  and  the  number  of  slaves  offered  by  indi- 
vidual slaveholders. 


Year. 

State. 

Slaves  Offered  by 

Number  Offered. 

1825 

Va. 

Name  not  given 

IOO 

" 

44 

David  Minge 

80  (approximately) 

•• 

44 

Charles  Henshaw 

60 

44 

44 

N.  C.  Crenshaw 

65 

" 

44 

Rev.  Cave  Jones 

a 

44 

44 

Rev.  John  Paxton 

ii 

•' 

Ky. 

Miss  Elizabeth  Moore 

40  (approximately) 

" 

N.  C. 

David  Patterson 

ii 

•' 

Md. 

Dickinson 

i 

41 

44 

Name  not  given 

20 

44 

? 

Rev.  Fletcher  Andrew 

30 

1826 

Va. 

Colonel  Smith 

70  or  80 

4< 

44 

H.  B.  Elder 

20 

44 

" 

Henry  Robertson 

7 

44 

" 

Miss  Patsy  Morris 

16 

44 

44 

A  clergyman 

30  (approximately) 

41 

44 

A  lady 

12  (approximately) 

44 

Md. 

David  Shriver 

30 

44 

Tenn. 

Sampson  David 

23 

44 

O. 

Rev.  S.  D.  Hoge 

i 

1827 

Va. 

Funston 

10 

44 

44 

Ward 

no 

44 

44 

Rev.  Robert  Cox 

30  (approximately) 

44 

44 

Col.  David  Bullock 

23 

44 

Md. 

Daniel  Murray 

i 

44 

>i 

J.  J.  Merrick 

3 

44 

44 

Name  not  given 

2 

44 

N.  C. 

William  Fletcher 

12 

41 

S.  C. 

M'Dearmid 

26 

44 

? 

Capt.  J.  D.  Henley 

I 

1828 

Va. 

Name  not  given 

17 

M 

14 

Name  not  given 

8 

44 

44 

Name  not  given 

S 

44 

" 

Name  not  given 

20  (approximately) 

44 

Ky. 

Name  not  given 

60  (approximately) 

" 

Ga. 

Name  not  given 

43 

1829 

Va. 

Rev.  T.  P.  Hunt 

18 

44 

44 

Edward  Colston 

6 

44 

Md. 

Miss  Margaret  Mercer 

IS 

44 

" 

J.  L.  Smith 

12 

44 

14 

Governor  Ridgeley 

400  (this  case  not  certain) 

1830 

Va. 

Dr.  Tilden 

6 

44 

44 

Pretlow 

3 

44 

44 

G.  W.  Holcomb 

5 

44 

44 

Name  not  given 

?  (one  family) 

525] 


COLONIZATION  AND  EMANCIPATION 


213 


Year. 

State. 

Slaves  Offered  by 

Number  Offered. 

1830 

Va. 

A  lady 

SO 

** 

44 

A  lady 

12 

41 

" 

Name  not  given 

?  (all  his  slaver 

•  « 

" 

W.  H.  Fitzhugh 

300  (approx-matelv^ 

44 

" 

Miss  Blackburn 

12 

" 

" 

Miss  Van  Meter 

7 

** 

4 

Name  not  given 

7 

" 

4 

John  Morton 

a 

" 

4 

Noah  Maund 

9 

" 

4 

John  Matthews 

6 

•  I 

4 

? 

2 

" 

4 

John  B.  Can- 

10 

44 

4 

Name  not  given 

6 

** 

' 

A  lady 

So 

" 

44 

A  lady 

i 

" 

44 

Mrs.  Merry 

4 

44 

44 

Mrs  Ann  Tinsley 

2 

" 

Md. 

F.  S.  Anderson 

6 

" 

44 

Name  not  given 

20 

" 

44 

Mr.  Bel! 

2 

44 

44 

J.  Hughes 

I 

" 

Ga. 

Joel  Early 

30 

44 

44 

Name  not  given 

I 

" 

44 

C.  Bolton 

9 

Tenn. 

Judge  Wm.  Brown 

IS 

" 

44 

Rev.  Williamson 

23 

44 

Ky. 

Richard  Bibb 

60 

1 

44 

J.  A.  Jacobs 

I 

1 

44 

W.  L.  Breckenridge 

14 

' 

Miss. 

Dr.  Silas  Hamilton 

22 

4 

? 

Francis  Kinlcck 

I 

' 

? 

Richard  Holmes 

30 

*' 

? 

J.  B.  Blackburn 

12 

1831 

Va. 

H.  Robinson 

I 

" 

44 

Dr.  Matthews 

I 

" 

44 

Rev.  John  Stockdell 

31 

" 

44 

William  Johnson 

12 

" 

44 

Name  not  given 

6 

It 

44 

Name  not  given 

3 

" 

Md. 

Thomas  Davis 

4 

" 

N.  C. 

Williams 

8 

" 

44 

Gen.  Jacobs 

7 

" 

Ky. 

L.  W.  Green 

i 

44 

14 

Lee  White 

? 

" 

Tenn. 

Name  not  given 

4 

44 

Miss. 

Mrs.  E,  Greenfield 

18 

1832 

Va. 

Dr.  Wilson 

3 

" 

44 

George  Reynolds 

7 

44 

44 

T.  O.  Taylor 

9 

" 

4 

Mrs.  A.  R.  Page 

IS 

" 

4 

Mrs.  A.  R.  Page 

14 

41 

4 

Rev.  M.  B.  Cox 

i 

•* 

4 

Name  not  given 

13 

" 

4 

Two  gentlemen 

II 

214 


THE   AMERICAN    COLONIZATION    SOCIETY 


[526 


Year. 

State. 

Slave*  Offered  by 

Number  Offered. 

1832 

Va. 

Name  not  given 

17  (approximately) 

" 

" 

Name  not  given 

14 

" 

" 

A  lady 

i 

" 

N.  C. 

J.  A.  Gray 

14 

" 

" 

Name  not  given 

7 

" 

" 

A  lady 

4 

" 

s.  c. 

Mr.  Stewart 

14 

" 

Ga. 

Dr.  Bradley 

46 

" 

Tenn. 

Name  not  given 

8 

1833 

Va. 

Dr.  Aylett  Hawes 

109 

" 

" 

Theophilus  Gamble 

2 

" 

" 

Robert  Coiner 

2 

•• 

" 

Silas  Henton 

a 

" 

" 

Rev.  Hanks 

9 

" 

Md. 

Col.  Wm.  Jones 

13 

" 

Ky. 

Wm.  O.  Dudley 

12 

" 

" 

Cyrus  Walker 

6 

" 

" 

Mrs.  Mary  Wycliffe 

7 

" 

" 

Rev.  J.  D.  Paxton 

5 

" 

** 

A.  M.  and  D.  Caldwell 

4 

" 

" 

Mrs.  Powell 

3 

" 

" 

Rev.  J.  C.  Young 

2 

" 

" 

Heirs  of  Dr.  A.  Todd 

4 

" 

" 

Jonathan  Becroft 

3 

" 

" 

Rev.  D.  Blackburn 

2 

11 

" 

James  Hood 

3 

" 

** 

Dr.  B.  Roberts 

I 

" 

" 

John  Holson 

I 

" 

" 

A.  J.  Alexander 

i 

" 

Tenn. 

George  Ewing 

10 

" 

" 

Dr.  McGehee 

i 

" 

" 

Robert  Caldwell 

i 

" 

Ga, 

Rev.  Ripley 

14 

" 

O. 

Benj.  Johnson 

6 

" 

111. 

Cyrus  Edwards 

i 

1834 

Va. 

Johnson  Cleveland 

? 

N.  C. 

Name  not  given 

4 

" 

Miss. 

Name  not  given 

19 

" 

Ga. 

Name  not  given 

i 

I83S 

Va. 

Isaac  Noves 

25 

' 

Thos.  Higginbotham 

So 

" 

1 

Name  not  given 

23 

" 

' 

Name  not  given 

7 

" 

1 

Rev.  J.  M.  Brown 

i 

" 

1 

Dawson 

So 

" 

• 

Gen.  Blackburn 

So 

" 

1 

James  Ogden 

5 

" 

' 

Name  not  given 

?  (several) 

" 

• 

Miss  Martha  Walker 

16 

" 

1   • 

Mrs.  A.  R.  Page 

4 

" 

• 

J.  T.  Atkinson 

?  (several) 

•' 

' 

Wever 

25 

" 

D.  C. 

Name  not  given 

i 

" 

Tenn. 

Rev.  F.  A.  Ross 

21 

527] 


COLONIZATION    AND  EMANCIPATION 


215 


Year. 

State. 

Slaves  Offered  by 

Numbered. 

I83S 

Tenn. 

Name  not  given 

20 

" 

" 

Alexander  Donelson 

20 

" 

" 

Name  not  given 

20 

" 

Ga. 

Name  not  given 

I 

44 

41 

Name  not  given 

8 

" 

La. 

H.  M.  Childers 

30 

" 

Miss. 

Name  not  given 

2o 

•' 

14 

William  Foster 

21 

" 

44 

Brazile 

? 

(four  families) 

" 

41 

Mr.  Randolph 

21 

" 

41 

Name  not  given 

ISO 

41 

? 

Name  not  given 

4 

Total  approximately  

3,300 

CHAPTER  V 

COLONIZATION  AND  THE  AFRICAN  SLAVE  TRADE 

The  American  Colonization  Society  was  organized  in 
1817.  Its  active  opposition  to  the  African  Slave  Trade 
began  that  same  year,  and  did  not  end  until  the  last  slaver 
had  been  driven  from  the  African  Coast.  Indeed,  within 
two  weeks  of  the  first  election  of  officers  of  the  Society,  a 
memorial  was  presented  to  Congress,  praying  that  body  to 
bestir  itself  to  put  an  end  to  the  traffic.1  The  following 
year  a  similar  memorial  was  presented.  It  was  the  Coloni- 
zationist  leader,  Charles  Fenton  Mercer,  who  secured  the 
passage  of  the  Anti-Slave  Trade  Act  of  March  3rd,  1819, 
and  the  passage  of  that  act  is  in  large  measure  due  to  the 
efforts  of  the  Colonization  Society.2  By  the  terms  of  the 
act,  Africans  illegally  taken  from  their  native  land  and 
recaptured  by  the  authorities  of  the  United  States  Govern- 
ment were  to  be  returned  to  the  coast  of  Africa.  It  pro- 
vided, further,  for  the  appointment  of  agents  of  the  United 
States  to  look  after  such  recaptured  slaves  upon  their 
return. 

President  Monroe,  who  construed  very  liberally  the  terms 
of  the  Act,  cooperated  with  the  Society,  sending  agents  and 
ships,  and  selecting  as  the  location  for  the  point  of  resettle- 
ment of  returned  natives  the  same  portion  of  the  African 
coast  as  that  occupied  by  the  Society.  In  short,  he  so  con- 
strued the  act  as  to  make  the  government  a  partner  in  the 
efforts  of  the  Colonizationists,  though  the  government  con- 
fined its  cooperation  to  the  purposes  set  forth  in  the  Act, 
the  selection  of  territory  as  an  asylum  for  recaptured  Afri- 
cans. It  was  under  this  unofficial  understanding  between 

1  African  Repository,  vol.  xviii,  p.  129  ff. 

2  Ibid.,  vol.  xv,  p.  300. 

216 


529]     COLONIZATION    AND   THE   AFRICAN    SLAVE   TRADE        2 1/ 

the  government  and  the  Society  that  Mills  and  Burgess 
were  sent  out  to  explore  the  coast  and  recommend  a  point 
for  the  settlement.  In  his  report  Burgess — for  Mills  had 
died  before  reaching  America — called  attention  to  the  de- 
struction caused  by  the  slave  trade,  and  recommended  as 
the  most  important  objects  the  Society  could  keep  in  mind, 
from  the  point  of  view  of  its  influence  upon  Africa :  ( I )  the 
suppression  of  the  slave  trade,  and  (2)  the  elevation  of  the 
natives.8 

In  1820  the  Society,  in  a  memorial,  urged  upon  Congress 
the  need  of  an  agreement  among  the  maritime  powers 
"  which  shall  leave  no  shelter  to  those  who  deserve  to  be 
considered  as  the  common  enemies  of  mankind."4  The 
committee  to  which  the  memorial  was  referred  reported  a 
bill  which  contained  a  provision  declaring  the  slave  trade 
to  be  piracy.  Again,  in  1822,  the  same  body  was  memorial- 
ized to  take  further  measures  in  opposition  to  the  slave 
trade,  and  was  advised  that  colonization  on  the  west  African 
coast  by  civilized  powers,  was  one  of  the  most  effective 
remedies  for  that  trade.  Late  in  February,  1823,  Mercer 
secured  a  unanimous  vote  in  the  House  declaring  slave  trad- 
ers pirates.5 

Indeed,  the  birth  of  that  settlement  which,  before  the  cen- 
tury was  half  passed,  was  to  become  the  Republic  of  Li- 
beria, must  be  considered  the  result  of  the  cooperation  of 
the  United  States  Government  and  the  group  of  coloniza- 
tion philanthropists.  The  first  endeavored  to  establish  an 
asylum  for  recaptured  Africans.  The  second  hoped  to  es- 
tablish a  home  for  those  free  negroes  from  America  who 
desired  to  be  free  not  only  from  physical  but  from  mental 

8  Origin,  Constitution,  and  Proceedings  of  American  Colonization 
Society,  MS.,  vol.  i,  p.  33  ff. 

4  African  Repository,  vol.  xviii,  p^.  129  ff. ;  Origin,  Constitution,, 
and  Proceedings  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  vol.  i,  pp. 
116-117. 

6 African  Repository,  vol.  xyiii,  p.  129 ff.;  Minutes  of  Board  of 
Managers  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  March  4,  1819, 
Dec.  10,  1819;  Origin,  Constitution,  and  Proceedings  of  American 
Colonization  Society,  MS.,  vol.  i,  p.  123  ff. 


2l8  THE   AMERICAN    COLONIZATION    SOCIETY  [530 

slavery,  for  nowhere  in  the  United  States  was  the  negro 
really  free  in  1820;  for  those  slaves  whose  masters,  under 
the  influence  of  moral  suasion,  might  desire  to  emancipate ; 
and  to  establish  a  colony  which  would  close  that  part  of  the 
African  coast  to  the  trader  in  West  Africa  negroes.  The 
first  direct  and  tangible  steps  taken  in  the  colonization  enter- 
prise were  taken  by  the  Government  rather  than  by  the 
Society.  The  first  vessel  sent  to  the  African  coast  was 
chartered  and  paid  for  by  the  Government.  The  first 
agents  received  salaries  from  the  government,  and  the  So- 
ciety was  backed  by  the  appropriation  of  $100,000  contained 
in  the  Act  of  iSiQ.6 

Already  by  1826  the  colony  had  become  so  effective  a  bar- 
rier to  the  slave-trade  that  a  French  trader  threatened  to  fit 
out  a  piratical  expedition  and  make  war  on  the  colony  for 
its  interference  with  his  business.7  In  1827  at  the  annual 
meeting  of  the  Society,  the  powers  of  Europe  and  America 
were  called  upon  to  adopt  further  restrictive  measures 
against  an  apparently  increasing  trade.  Mercer  there  called 
attention  to  the  fact  that  in  1824  two  hundred  and  eighteen 
slave  vessels  had  carried  away  from  their  homes  120,000 
victims.  He  wished  the  time  to  come  when  the  trade  would 
be  stamped  with  "the  seal  of  indelible  infamy."8  At  this 
time  Dr.  William  Thornton,  doubtless  with  the  object  of 
making  the  colony  an  effective  barrier  against  the  trade,  was 
urging  the  Society  to  obtain  territory  for  a  thousand  miles 
along  the  coast,  even  if  the  width  of  the  territory  was  not 
more  than  a  single  mile.9 

Certainly  those  Americans  who  were  fighting  the  traffic 
could  have  asked  for  no  more  effective  or  energetic  colonial 
agent  than  was  now  in  the  colony,  Jehudi  Ashmun.  Under 
his  administration  and,  indeed,  largely  due  to  his  exertion, 

6  27th  Cong.,  3d  sess.,  H.  Kept.  No.  283,  pp.  247-249. 

7  Minutes  of  Board  of  Managers  of  American  Colonization  So- 
ciety, MS.,  May  23,  1826. 

8  African  Repository,  vol.  ii,  pp.  357-358. 

9  Letters  of  American  Colonization   Society,  MS.,  Thornton  to 
Gurley,  April  n,  1827. 


531]     COLONIZATION    AND   THE   AFRICAN    SLAVE   TRADE        2 19 

the  slave  trade  had  ceased  it  seemed  along  the  hundred  miles 
of  coast  over  which  the  Liberian  settlers,  not  over  1200  souls 
in  1828,  assumed  jurisdiction.  Rev.  Leonard  Bacon,  in  his 
eulogy  upon  Ashmun  in  1828,  declared  of  Cape  Montserado 
that,  while  a  few  years  ago  it  was  "  literally  consecrated  to 
the  devil "  and  cursed  as  a  port  of  entry  for  the  unspeakable 
slave  ship,  at  the  time  of  Ashmun's  death  "  for  a  hundred 
miles  no  slave  trader  dares  to  spread  his  canvas."10 

Dr.  Randall  went  out  as  colonial  agent  upon  the  death  of 
Mr.  Ashmun.  He  urged  the  building  and  improving  of 
fortifications  in  the  colony  in  order  that  it  might  be  effective 
in  its  fight  against  the  slave  trader.  He  recommended  that 
a  government  vessel  should  cruise  for  some  months  along 
the  Liberian  coast  and  watch  the  movements  of  the  trader. 
Officers  of  the  Society  in  this  country  called  upon  the  Presi- 
dent and  Secretary  of  the  Navy  in  order  to  secure  action 
upon  the  agent's  request.11  The  official  effort  was  seconded 
by  the  Philadelphia  Quaker,  Elliot  Cresson,  who  wrote :  "  I 
wish  as  our  friend  Key  has  influence  with  Old  Hickory,  thee 
would  occasionally  hint  to  him  the  advantage  which  we 
might  derive,  from  certain  welltimed  suggestion,  such  as 
keeping  a  sharp  lookout  on  the  African  Coast  by  a  swift 
cruiser — or  if  possible  making  her  a  packet  on  her  outward 
voyage."12 

During  the  years  1830-1839  the  Society  was  too  busy  try- 
ing to  make  its  resources  meet  its  expenditures  and  trying  to 
take  care  of  the  negroes  offered  to  it,  or  settled  in  its  colony, 
or  meeting  the  furious  opposition  of  the  Garrisonians,  to 
continue  its  direct  efforts  toward  the  abolition  of  the  slave 
trade ;  and  in  1839  the  general  agent  reported  an  alarming 
increase  in  the  number  of  African  victims  taken  away  from 
the  very  vicinity  of  the  colony.  The  influence  of  that  trade 
had  involved  the  neighboring  tribes  in  a  war  which  endan- 

10  L.  Bacon,  Funeral  Oration  on  Jehudi  Ashmun,  New  Haven, 
Conn.,  1828. 

11  Minutes  of  Board  of  Managers  of  American  Colonization  So- 
ciety, MS.,  April  13,  1829. 

12  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Cresson  to  Gur- 
ley,  Philadelphia,  Pa.,  December  7,  1829. 


22O  THE  AMERICAN    COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [532 

gered  the  peace  of  the  colony,  and  Wilkeson  pressed  the 
matter  before  the  Secretary  of  the  Navy.18 

When  the  Society  was  reorganized  in  1839  there  were 
sent  to  the  colonial  governor,  Thomas  Buchanan,  positive 
instructions  urging  the  passage  of  a  law  forbidding  "any 
communication  between  the  citizens  of  Liberia  and  the  slave 
traders,"  and  punishing  Liberian  citizens  violating  the  law 
"  in  the  same  manner  as  are  citizens  or  subjects  of  any  civi- 
lized State,  who,  are  guilty  of  dealing  with  or  succoring  an 
enemy  in  time  of  war."  They  urged  the  death  penalty  for 
any  participation  by  a  Liberian  in  the  business  of  the  trader. 
The  reason  for  these  strict  instructions  will  be  understood 
when  it  is  stated  that  there  were  some — there  appears  no- 
evidence  that  many  were  guilty  of  it — among  the  Liberians. 
who  had  themselves  been  redeemed  from  the  chains  of  slav- 
ery, who  were  actively  engaged  in  assisting  the  slave  trader ; 
and  the  Society  felt  that  the  whole  colonization  scheme  was. 
jeopardized  by  such  conduct.  Indeed,  Judge  Wilkeson 
thought  that  the  strongest  tie  that  bound  many  persons  to 
the  colonization  cause  was  their  belief  that  it  was  the  only 
hope  of  putting  an  end  to  a  very  unpopular  business.  Wilke- 
son commented :  "  It  was  natural  to  suppose  that  those  who 
had  returned  to  the  land  of  their  fathers  .  .  .  would  urge 
increasing  war  against  this  system  of  cruelty  so  long  prac- 
ticed upon  their  brethren."  He  thought  that  if  it  became 
known  publicly  that  colonists  had  aided  the  slavers,  "the 
colonies  would  be  denounced  and  execrated  from  one  end 
of  the  Union  to  the  other."14 

The  new  Governor  was  another  Ashmun  in  his  hatred  of 
the  slaver  and  his  energy  in  routing  him  from  the  neighbor- 
hood of  the  colony.  During  the  first  year  of  his  adminis- 
tration he  brought  about  the  capture  of  a  slaving  ship  carry- 
ing the  flag  of  the  United  States  and  sent  her  to  America 
for  trial.  She  was  the  schooner  Euphrates.15  He  further 

18  Ibid.,  Wilkeson  to  Secretary  of  the  Navy,  February  12,  1839. 

14  Journal  of  Executive  Committee  of  American  Colonization  So- 
ciety, MS.,  July  25,  1839. 

15  African  Repository,  vol.  xvii,  pp.  246-247. 


533]     COLONIZATION  AND  THE  AFRICAN   SLAVE   TRADE       221 

went  boldly  out  with  a  company  of  colonists  and  captured 
out  of  their  prisons  a  number  of  native  Africans  who  were 
held  in  waiting  for  the  arrival  of  the  next  slaver.16 

There  was  not  a  little  difference  of  opinion  as  to  the  most 
effective  means  of  abolishing  the  trade.  There  were  those 
who  thought  that  it  would  automatically  cease  as  slavery  was 
abolished  in  the  civilized  nations  that  still  endured  it.  There 
were  others  who  supposed  that  the  iniquity  would  never  be 
suppressed  until  the  maritime  powers  jointly  and  constantly 
patrolled  the  waters  along  the  west  African  coast.  But  in 
the  early  forties  the  predominating  view,  it  seems,  was  that 
the  planting  of  colonies  along  the  west  coast  would  make 
impossible  a  traffic  between  the  slave  traders  and  the  natives 
of  the  interior,  and  that  such  colonies,  planted  by  the  civilized 
powers,  presented  the  only  efficient  remedy  for  that  traffic. 

Thomas  Foxwell  Buxton,  who  had  been  so  much  inter- 
ested in  the  abolition  of  slavery  in  the  West  Indies,  himself 
believed  that  that  very  abolition  had  stimulated  a  disguised 
form  of  the  slave  trade  with  that  colony.  The  recently 
emancipated  negroes  of  those  Islands  refused  to  work,  and 
the  result  was  the  importation  of  so-called  free  negro  labor 
from  the  African  coast.  Those  imported  were,  many  of 
them,  either  stolen  outright  or  brought  in  ignorance  to  the 
West  Indies,  and  the  result  was  the  legitimating  of  what 
had  before  been  illegal.17  This  was  also  Perry's  view.18 
Buxton  believed  that  the  only  satisfactory  remedy  was  the 
establishment  along  the  coast  of  civilized  colonies  which 
would  not  endure  the  slave  trade  within  their  jurisdictions 
and  which  would  provide  an  effective  barrier  between  those 
who  operated  slave  vessels  along  the  coast  and  those  within 
the  interior  who  were  willing  to  sell  their  fellow  Africans. 

In  this  view  the  Colonizationists  of  America  heartily  con- 
curred.19 Indeed  they  had  had  a  practical  verification  of 

16  For  an  interesting  account  qf  the  expedition  see  African  Re- 
pository, vol.  xv,  pp.  277-282. 

17  Sir  T.  F.  Buxton,  The  African  Slave  Trade  and  Its  Remedy, 
passim;  London  Quarterly  Review,  March,  1839. 

18  African  Repository,  vol.  xvii,  pp.  85-86. 

19  Ibid.,  vol.  xvii,  pp.  246-247. 


222  THE  AMERICAN    COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [534 

the  value  of  this  method.  Bassa  Cove,  one  of  the  Liberian 
settlements,  had  once  been  the  seat  of  the  slave  trade.  From 
five  to  six  thousand  natives  had  been  packed  into  slave 
vessels  and  taken  from  that  point  annually ;  after  the  settle- 
ment of  that  point  by  the  Colonizationists  the  trade  was 
completely  broken  up.  Cape  Montserado  itself  had  once 
been  a  depot  for  the  detention  of  captured  natives.  Slavers 
touched  there  and  carried  away  annually  from  two  to  three 
thousand  native  Africans  into  slavery.  After  the  settle- 
ment of  the  cape  and  its  government  by  the  Colonizationists 
the  slave  trade  ceased.20 

There  is  abundant  evidence  to  the  value  of  the  colony  as 
a  contributor  to  the  suppression  of  the  slave  trade.  In 
April,  1842,  Secretary  of  State  Webster  made  inquiries  of 
Captains  Charles  H.  Bell  and  John  S.  Paine,  both  of  whom 
had  seen  service  along  the  west  African  coast  and  were 
familiar  with  the  influence  exerted  by  the  colony  of  Li- 
beria, as  to  the  length  of  coast  along  which  the  trade 
was  carried  on.  Those  officers*  replied  that  the  distance 
from  the  northernmost  to  the  southernmost  points  along  the 
coast,  where  the  slave  trader  put  in  for  slaves  was  3600 
miles,  but  that  the  influence  of  the  British,  French,  and 
especially  the  American  settlements  was  so  directly  hostile 
to,  and  effective  against,  the  trade,  that  from  this  extent  of 
coast  should  be  subtracted  600  miles,  leaving  only  3000 
miles  of  coast  along  which  the  slavers  actually  carried  on 
their  work.21  Captain  Arabin,  of  Her  Majesty's  Navy,  tes- 
tified :  "  Wherever  the  influence  of  Liberia  extends,  the 
slave  trade  has  been  abandoned  by  the  natives,  and  the 
peaceful  pursuits  of  legitimate  commerce  established  in  its 
place."22 

M.  C.  Perry,  who  had  commanded  the  United  States  Na- 
val forces  on  the  west  coast  of  Africa,  wrote  in  1844 :  "  So 
far  as  the  influence  of  the  colonists  has  extended,  it  has  been 

20  Ibid.,  vol.  xvii,  p.  248. 

21  27th  Cong.,  3d  sess.,  H.  Kept,  No.  283,  pp.  768-769. 

22  African  Repository,  vol.  xvii,  p.  331,  Nov.,  1841. 


535]     COLONIZATION   AND   THE   AFRICAN    SLAVE   TRADE        223 

exerted  to  suppress  the  slave  trade,  and  their  endeavors  in 
this  respect  have  been  eminently  successful;  and  it  is  by 
planting  these  settlements  .  .  .  along  the  whole  extent  of 
coasts,  from  Cape  Verde  to  Benguela,  that  the  exportation 
of  slaves  will  be  most  effectually  prevented."'  He  favored 
appropriations  from  Congress  in  aid  of  the  Society  for  this 
purpose  as  well  as  others.23  Two  years  later  he  declared: 
"It  is  useless  to  talk  of  destroying  this  vile  traffic  in  any 
other  way  than  by  belting  the  whole  coast  with  Christian 
settlements,  unless  the  European  powers  should  follow  the 
example  of  the  United  States  and  declare  it  to  be  piracy, 
and  then  faithfully  enforce  the  law,"  and  he  thought  that 
at  that  time  the  only  powers  that  were  in  earnest  about  the 
destruction  of  the  trade  were  the  United  States  and  Great 
Britain.24 

Not  only  did  the  colonial  governors  effectively  prohibit 
the  slave  trade  within  the  jurisdiction  of  the  colony,  but 
they  also  provided  needed  information  as  to  the  points  along 
the  coast  at  which  the  trade  was  still  carried  on.  Upon 
several  occasions  reports  were  received  that  certain  points 
along  the  coast  and  surrounded  by  the  territory  of  the  col- 
ony— for  it  was  years  before  the  colony  obtained  exclusive 
jurisdiction  over  a  continuous  line  of  coast — were  used  as 
centres  of  the  trade.  The  Society  almost  invariably  set  at 
once  to  work  to  purchase  these  points.23  Thousands  of  dol- 
lars were  given  by  Americans  for  this  specific  purpose. 
Governor  Roberts  in  1843  notified  the  Society  that  at  a 
single  depot,  between  Cape  Mount  and  Cape  Palmas,  both 
surrounded  by  Liberian  territory,  four  hundred  slaves  had 
but  recently  been  taken  away  in  slavers.  At  once  the  ques- 
tion of  the  purchase  of  that  territory  was  agitated  by  the 
Directors  of  the  Society.26 

28  African  Repository,  June,  1844,  vol.  xx,  pp.  167-168;  Letter  of 
M.  C.  Perry  to  David  Henshaw,  Secretary  of  the  Navy,  January  4, 
1844- 

24  African  Repository,  vol.  xxii,  pp.  85-86,  March,  1846. 

25  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Gurley  to  Rev. 
S.  Cornelius,  July  28,  1843. 

26  Ibid.,  Gurley  to  Cornelius,  July  28,  1843 !  Journal  of  Board  of 
Directors  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  vol.  iv,  p.  24. 


224  THE  AMERICAN    COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [536 

By  1845  there  were,  it  seems,  but  two  points  along  a  coast 
line  of  seven  hundred  miles,  over  which  the  influence  of  the 
colony  extended,  where  the  slavers  continued  to  frequent, 
and  they  were  points  which  the  Society  had  not  had  the 
means  to  purchase.  It  should  be  remembered  that  twenty 
years  before  the  whole  of  that  coast  line  was  dotted  with 
depots,  slave  factories  as  they  were  called,  where  the  slaver 
came  to  take  away  hundreds  of  slaves  in  a  single  vessel, 
scores  of  the  human  cargo  perishing  before  the  vessel  had 
reached  its  destination,  while  there  were,  in  1845,  but  two 
depots  that  remained,  and  they  without  the  limits  of  the 
Colony.  It  was  probably  a  fair  estimate  that  the  Society 
made,  that  it  was  saving  every  year,  or  was  the  leading 
instrument  in  saving  from  perpetual  bondage  in  some  other 
land  or  from  a  horrible  death  on  a  slave  ship,  20,000 
Africans.27 

If  one  may  venture  to  estimate  the  number  of  native 
Africans  saved  from  either  of  these  alternatives  by  the 
influence  of  the  American  Colonization  Society,  would  it 
be  too  much  to  say  that  not  fewer  than  100,000  negroes 
were  in  this  way  saved  to  freedom?  When  the  Garrisonian 
asked  the  Colonizationist :  "What  are  you  doing  to  bring 
about  the  immediate  emancipation  of  the  slaves  in  the 
United  States?"  the  Colonizationist  could  and  did  reply: 
"  We  are  doing  all  we  can  to  secure  the  entire  abolition  of 
slavery  in  the  United  States  as  soon  as  may  be  consistent 
with  constitutional  guarantees,  peace,  and  the  preservation 
of  the  American  Union.  What  are  you  doing  to  bring  about 
the  immediate  abolition  of  the  slave  trade?  "  And  the  Gar- 
risonian was  silent  on  the  efforts  of  the  Society  to  bring  to 
a  speedy  end  that  outlawed  and  inhuman  traffic. 

For  many  years  there  was  active  cooperation  between  the 
Society  and  the  Government  in  relation  to  this  trade.  In 
1844  the  Society  kept  an  agent  in  Liberia  whose  duty  it  was 
to  deliver  parcels  and  packages  sent  to  the  American  squad- 
ron patrolling  the  African  coast  waters.  Also  the  Govern- 

87  African  Repository,  May,  1845,  vol.  xxi,  p.  145  ff. 


537]     COLONIZATION   AND  THE  AFRICAN   SLAVE  TRADE       22$ 

ment  was  allowed  to  land,  free  of  duty,  at  the  port  of 
Monrovia,  all  provisions,  stores,  and  supplies  used  by  the 
squadron.28  It  also  received  hundred  of  recaptured  Africans 
and  settled  them  in  Liberia.  The  largest  single  cargo  of 
slaves  thus  sent  to  Liberia  was  that  sent  in  the  "  Pons  "  in 
1846,  for  whose  support  the  Government  paid  the  Society 
thirty-odd  thousand  dollars.29 

The  Society  did  not  hesitate  to  investigate  cases  in  which 
citizens  of  New  York  or  the  New  England  States  were  re- 
ported to  be  engaged  in  operating  vessels  which  were  ac- 
tively engaged  in  the  slave  trade.30  And  when  there  was 
talk  of  abrogating  that  part  of  the  Webster-Ashburton  treaty 
which  related  to  the  patrolling  of  the  waters  along  the  Afri- 
can coast,  and  at  other  times  when  there  was  some  discus- 
sion of  the  advisability  of  either  withdrawing  or  diminishing 
the  size  of  the  squadron  kept  in  those  waters,  the  leaders  of 
the  Society  consistently  protested  against  such  withdrawal 
or  diminution.31 

It  will  be  of  interest  to  note  the  opinion  of  Secretary  of 
State  Everett  in  1853.  Everett  said : 

Wherever  a  colony  is  established  on  the  coast  of  Africa  under  the 
direction  of  a  Christian  power  in  Europe  or  America,  there  the  slave 
trade  disappears ;  not  merely  from  the  coast  of  the  colony,  but  from 
the  whole  interior  of  the  country  which  found  an  outlet  at  any 
point  on  the  coast.  .  .  .  The  last  slave  mart  in  that  region,  the  Gal- 
linas,  has,  within  a  short  time,  I  believe,  come  within  the  jurisdic- 
tion of  the  American  colony  of  Liberia.  Now,  along  that  whole 
line  of  coast  .  .  .  from  every  port  and  every  harbor  of  which  the 
foreign  slave  trade  was  carried  on — within  the  memory  of  man,  it 
has  entirely  disappeared.  .  .  .  And  what  career  is  there  opened  for 
any  colored  man  in  Europe  or  America,  more  praiseworthy,  more 
inviting  than  thus  to  form  as  it  were,  in  his  own  person  a  portion 

28  Journal  of  Executive  Committee  of  American  Colonization  So- 
ciety, MS.,  June  6,  1844,  pp.  381-383. 

29  Ibid.,  May  I,  1851,  p.  187;  Minutes  of  Board  of  Directors  of 
American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  January  16,  1861,  pp.  367-368; 
January  22,  1862,  p.  380. 

80  Letters  of  American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  Tracy  to  Mc- 
Lain,  Boston,  April  23,   1846;  Minutes  of  Board  of  Directors  of 
American  Colonization  Society,  MS.,  January  18,  1855,  p.  218. 

81  Minutes  of  Board  of  Directors  of  American  Colonization  So- 
ciety, MS.,  January  20,  1853,  p.  120;  January  18,  1855,  pp.  213-214. 

15 


226  THE  AMERICAN   COLONIZATION   SOCIETY  [538 

of  that  living  cordon  stretching  along  the  coast  and  barring  its 
whole  extent  from  the  approaches  .of  this  traffic.32 

Professor  Hart,  commenting  upon  the  results  of  the  Colo- 
nization movement,  says  that,  with  the  backing  of  the  Fed- 
eral Government  and  its  auxiliary  societies  the  Society  was 
yet  not  able  to  oversome  "distance,  malaria,  savage  neigh- 
bors, and  a  tropical  climate."33  If  the  positions  taken  in 
this  study  have  been  successfully  maintained,  that  statement 
is  inadequate.  Not  only  were  all  those  difficulties,  except 
distance,  satisfactorily  overcome,  but,  from  the  point  of 
view  of  Africa  alone,  there  were  brought  about  two  impor- 
tant results :  ( i )  the  establishment  upon  the  west  African 
coast  of  a  model  republic  for  Africans,  and  (2)  the  salva- 
tion of  many  thousands  of  natives  from  the  holds  of  miser- 
able slave  ships.  If  viewed  alone  in  the  light  of  its  influ- 
ence upon  Africa,  was  not  this  something?  Indeed,  was  it 
not  worth  the  effort  required  to  bring  the  Society  into  being 
and  to  preserve  it  for  so  many  years  ? 

32  Edward  Everett,  Address  at  Anniversary  of  American  Coloni- 
zation Society,  MS.,  January  18,  1853. 
83  Hart,  p.  163. 


INDEX 


Abolitionists,  on  unhealthfulness 
of  Liberia,  55;  leading  Garri- 
sonians  once  Colonizationists, 
90-91 ;  rise  of  Abolition  oppo- 
sition to  Colonization,  90,  94- 
95 ;  effect  of  opposition,  124, 
136-141,  157-166;  Garrisonians 
and  radical  slaveholders  the 
Colonizationist's  bitterest  en- 
emies, 125 ;  debates  over  Colo- 
nization, 125-126;  two  classes 
of,  126;  radical  Abolition 
founded  upon  a  sectional  sen- 
timent, 127,  138-139,  166; 
views  on  slavery  and  the 
Union,  compared  with  views 
of  Colonizationists,  127,  146- 
149;  methods  used  in  criticis- 
ing Colonization,  128-136; 
amount  of  propaganda,  140; 
Abolitionist  and  Colonization- 
ist  views  of  slavery  contrasted, 
142-145, 151 ;  abusive  language 
to  slaveholders,  152;  injustice 
of  such  language,  152-154; 
confused  with  Colonization- 
ists in  the  South,  160;  Aboli- 
tion and  the  division  in  the 
Methodist  Church,  163-166 ; 
cooperation  between  Aboli- 
tionists and  Colonizationists 
urged,  1828,  166;  wherein 
Abolitionist  criticism  failed, 
171-172;  propaganda  discour- 
ages emancipations,  172-175 ; 
Birney  on  the  effects  of  Abo- 
lition upon  the  South,  174- 
175 ;  effect  of  opposition  to 
Colonization  on  the  Middle 
States,  177;  Colonizationists 
tend  to  become  moderate  Abo- 
litionists, 180-214. 

American  Colonization  Society, 
a  national  movement,  9-10,  75, 
loo,  127 ;  influence  not  to  be 
measured  by  number  of  ne- 
groes sent  to  Liberia,  u  ;  mo(- 
tives  of  organizers,  47-50; 


slaveholders  as  presidents  of, 
74;  effect  of  Pro-Slavery  Ar- 
gument on  Colonizationist 
sentiment  in  the  South,  155- 
156;  effect  of  Southampton 
Insurrection  on  sentiment  re- 
garding, in  Va.  and  Md.,  92 ; 
organization  of,  46-47,  50-51,, 
60;  finances  of,  57-65,  77-78, 
84-^5,  88,  90,  101-107,  123-124  ; 
geographical  distribution  of 
contributions,  65,  123-124 ; 
seeks  financial  aid  from  Con- 
gress, 54,  70-71 ;  investigation 
of  Society's  debt,  103-104; 
auxiliary  societies,  61 ;  senti- 
ment toward,  in  the  South,  58- 
59,  78-88,  92;  attitude  of  New 
England  clergy,  63-64;  expe- 
ditions sent  out,  55,  67,  68; 
character  of  emigrants,  89; 
table  of  emigrants,  1820-1830, 
89;  cost  to  Society  per  emi- 
grant, 88;  attitude  of  religious 
denominations,  78-79;  attitude 
of  state  legislatures,  79-80; 
Clay's  optimism,  77;  dissatis- 
faction of  auxiliary  societies, 
105-106;  secession  of  auxil- 
iaries, 95-101 ;  demand  for  re- 
organization, 106;  reorganiza- 
tion, 1 10-122;  a  new  constitu- 
tion proposed,  115-116;  adopt- 
ed, 120;  attitude  toward  the 
Union,  145,  150,  166;  Birney's 
and  Gerrit  Smith's  reasons  for 
deserting,  176;  Colonization 
and  Abolition  confused  in  the 
South,  160;  opposition  to,  in 
North  and  West,  90;  Aboli- 
tionist opposition,  90,  94-95 ; 
effect  of,  136,  157-166;  effect 
of  Colonization  movement 
upon  emancipations,  180-214; 
Colonization  Society  opposes 
African  slave  trade,  215-225; 
number  of  Africans  saved 
from  slavery  by,  223.  See  also 


228 


INDEX 


[540 


Abolition,  Emancipation,  Gar- 
rison, Slavery,  Slave  Trade, 
etc. 

Anti-Slave-Trade  Act  of  1819, 
influence  of  Colonization  So- 
ciety in  securing  passage  of, 
54,  215 ;  President  Monroe's 
interpretation  of,  55,  215-216. 

Ashmun,  Jehudi,  sent  to  Africa, 
68;  Ashmun  and  the  slave 
trade,  217-218. 

Ayres,  Dr.  Eli,  arrives  in  Africa 
as  agent,  67;  Liberia  ceded  to 
Ayres  and  Stockton,  68;  in- 
structed to  purchase  additional 
territory  in  Africa,  69. 

Birney,  James  G.,  once  a  Colo- 
nizationist,  90,  91 ;  on  detach- 
ing Virginia  from  the  slave 
States  by  a  scheme  of  eman- 
cipation and  colonization,  174- 
175;  reason  given  for  desert- 
ing the  Colonizationists,  176; 
Garrison  inquires  for,  178. 

Breckenridge,  Robert  J.,  167;  on 
relation  of  Colonizationists  to 
slaveholders,  169;  on  influence 
of  Colonization  Society  on 
emancipations,  187. 

Caldwell,  E.  B.,  43-44,  46,  181. 

Calhoun,  John  C,  190. 

Carey,  Mathew,  161. 

Carroll,  Charles,  of  Carrollton, 
74- 

Church,  attitude  of  Methodist 
toward  slavery  and  the  So- 
ciety, 10,  79,  163-164;  Presby- 
terian, 78,  91 ;  Friends  (Quak- 
ers), 78;  Episcopal,  79;  Dutch 
Reformed,  79;  Congregation- 
al, 79;  Unitarian,  79;  effect  of 
abolition  opposition  on  Colo- 
nization sentiment  in  the 
churches,  138,  139,  163 ;  slavery 
and  the  division  in  the  Meth- 
odist Church,  163-166. 

Clay,  Henry,  51 ;  on  the  property 
value  of  slaves  in  the  South, 
21 ;  on  the  future  of  slavery, 
23-24 ;  attitude  toward  slavery, 
29;  on  the  status  of  free  ne- 
groes, 33;  on  colonization,  39; 
organization  of  American  Col- 
onization Society,  46;  officer 


in,  51 ;  speech  at  annual  meet- 
ing, 1827,  urging  help  from 
Federal  Government,  76-77 ; 
on  the  gradual  abolition  of 
slavery  through  colonization, 
76-77;  politics  and  Coloniza- 
tion, 83-84;  on  danger  to 
Union,  from  Abolitionist  view 
of  slavery,  147-148 ;  on  effects 
of  Garrisonian  Abolition,  161. 

Cocke,  General  John  H.,  82-83, 
153-154; 

Colonization,  Maryland  House 
of  Representatives  on  slavery 
and,  30;  Gerrit  Smith  on,  32; 
essential  to  the  welfare  of  the 
free  negro,  37;  projects  be- 
fore 1817,  39-44;  as  the  solu- 
tion of  the  negro  problem, 
45-46;  a  middle  state  move- 
ment, 49;  a  means  of  abolish- 
ing slavery,  50;  effect  upon 
free  negro,  52;  growth  of  in- 
terest in,  75 ;  Clay's  views  of 
effect  of,  on  slavery,  76-77; 
politics  and,  83-84;  coloniza- 
tion an  aid  to  emancipation, 
90;  Birney  advocates  emanci- 
pation and  colonization,  for 
Virginia,  174-175;  not  the  so- 
lution of  the  negro  problem, 
177;  effect  of,  on  emancipa- 
tions, 1817-1850, 180-214;  cause 
of  the  Colonization  Society's 
influence,  187. 

Connecticut,  79. 

Cotton,  155. 

Delaware,  79. 

DeTocqueville,  A.,  on  slavery  in 
the  U.  S.,  19-20,  31. 

Dew,  Thomas,  Pro-Slavery  Ar- 
gument, lo-n ;  effect  of,  on 
the  South,  155,  156. 

Early,  Bishop  John,  166. 

Emancipation,  American  Colo- 
nization Society  and,  n,  50, 
51,  85,  162,  169,  173-174,  181 ; 
effect  of  Colonization  upon, 
180-214;  Maryland  House  of 
Representatives  on,  30;  atti^ 
tude  of  South  toward,  30-31 ; 
attitude  of  slaveholders,  38- 
39 ;  Bishop  Meade  on  effect  of 
Colonization  on,  49;  legis- 


S4i] 


INDEX 


229 


lative  acts  restricting,  90; 
views  of  Garrisonians  and 
Colonizationists  compared  and 
contrasted,  127,  142-145;  war 
with  Great  Britain  advocated 
as  a  means  of  emancipating 
the  negro,  134;  effect  of  Abo- 
lition on,  in  New  Orleans, 
160;  slaves  offered  freedom 
on  condition  of  their  removal 
to  Liberia,  169;  Birney  advo- 
cates general  scheme  of  eman- 
cipation and  colonization  for 
Va.,  174-175;  records  of,  diffi- 
cult to  obtain,  180;  Mass, 
contributes  to  Society  on  con- 
dition that  freed  slaves  be  sent 
to  Liberia,  185 ;  influences  dis- 
couraging emancipation,  189- 
194;  table  of  emancipations, 
1825-1833,  211-214;  estimates 
of  number  of  emancipated 
slaves  sent  to  Liberia,  214. 
Everett,  Edward,  36,  214-225. 

Fitzhugh,  William  H.,  48,  57,  59, 
85,  IPS- 

Free  Negro,  Mass.  Senate  on, 
28-29  J  effect  of  increase  on 
emancipations,  29 ;  property 
holdings  among,  in  Virginia, 
31 ;  DeTocqueville  on,  31 ; 
sentiments  of  various  sections 
toward,  28-37;  danger  in  im- 
mediate general  emancipation, 
142-143;  attitude  of  Coloniza- 
tion Society  toward,  1,43,  182"; 
effect  of  Colonization  enter- 
prise upon,  162;  Gerrit  Smith 
accuses  Colonization  Society 
of  neglecting,  176. 

Frelinghuysen,  Theodore,  80. 

Friends  (Quakers),  Society  of, 
64. 


Garrison,  William  Lloyd,  90,  91 ; 
hostility  to  Colonization,  125- 
179;  views  on  slavery  and  the 
Union,  compared  with  those 
of  Colonizationists,  127,  142- 
149,  150;  methods  of  criticism, 
128-136;  effect  of  opposition 
to  Colonization,  136-141,  157- 
166,  177,  178;  sectional  basis 
of  Garrisonism,  138-139;  Gar- 
risonians in  politics,  139; 


i 


propaganda,  140 ;  resolutions 
on  dissolution  of  the  Union, 
149;  language  to  slaveholders, 

152-154- 

Georgia,  49,  81. 

Giles,  William  B.,  83-84. 

Grimke,  Sarah  M.,  178. 

Gurley,  R.  R.,  sent  to  Liberia, 
73  ;  proposes  a  constitution  for 
Liberia,  74-75 ;  reports  on  con- 
ditions in,  75 ;  influence  in 
Colonization  movement,  73- 
74;  on  the  rise  of  Abolition 
opposition,  94-95 ;  on  relations 
between  parent  and  auxiliary 
societies,  99,  100;  views  on  re- 
organization of  the  Society, 
117-118;  debates  with  Abo- 
litionists, 126;  on  the  effect  of 
Garrisonian  opposition,  137- 
138;  on  Abolition  and  Coloni- 
zation propaganda,  140;  view 
of  the  American  slave  system, 
157;  on  the  purchase  of  free- 
dom for  slaves,  183. 

Harrison,  J.  B.,  reply  of,  to  Pro- 
Slavery  Argument,  II,  155- 
156;  encouragement  given  by 
Colonization  Society,  n;  con- 
fers with  New  Englanders, 
75;  hopes  for  abolition  of 
slavery,  167. 

Hart,  A.  B.,  225. 

Hopkins,  Dr.  Samuel,  39-41. 

Illinois,  162. 
Indiana,  79,  80. 

Jackson,  Andrew,  Vice-Presi- 
dent  of  Colonization  Society, 
5i. 

Jefferson,  Thomas,  40,  41-42. 

Kentucky,  79,  173,  187. 

Key,  Francis  Scott,  attitude  to- 
ward slavery,  17-19;  and  the 
organization  of  the  Coloniza- 
tion Society,  43-44,  5* ',  agent 
for  Colonization,  57;  on  effect 
of  Abolitionism  on  welfare  of 
the  negro,  160;  on  number  of 
slaves  whose  freedom  could 
be  secured  on  condition  of  re- 
moval to  Africa,  169,  186; 
hope  of  ultimate  abolition  of 
slavery,  175 ;  on  Colonization 
and  abolition  of  slavery,  181. 


230 


INDEX 


[542 


Latrobe,  J.  H.  B.,  on  slavery, 
23;  a  leader  in  the  Maryland 
Colonization  Society,  61 ;  rea- 
son given  for  secession  of 
Maryland  auxiliary  society,  97. 

Liberator,  The,  on  motives  of 
organizers  of  Colonization 
Society,  47;  charges  against 
Colonizationists,  100,  169-170; 
amount  of  space  given  to  op- 
position to  Colonization,  125, 
132;  character  of  criticism, 
130;  exults  over  the  debt  of 
Colonization  Society,  132 ;  lan- 
guage to  slaveholders,  152-154. 

Liberia,  ship  line  between  U.  S. 
and,  proposed,  35;  healthful- 
ness  of,  55-57,  69-70;  bad 
news  from,  1820;  66-67;  ex- 
peditions to,  55,  67;  deaths  of 
agents,  67;  land  purchased, 
67;  land  ceded  to  Stockton 
and  Ayres,  68;  considered  as 
a  trust  by  the  Colonization 
Society,  68;  American  flag 
raised,  68;  the  colony  named, 
71 ;  discontent  among  colo- 
nists, 71-73;  constitution  pro- 
posed for,  75;  Gurley's  icport 
on  conditions  in,  75 ;  number 
of  emigrants  and  cost  per 
emigrant  to,  88-89;  table  of 
emigrants  sent  by  Society  to, 
89;  character  of  emigrants, 
89 ;  independent  settlements  of 
auxiliary  societies,  95;  unwise 
administration  in,  102,  107- 
no;  financial  difficulties  limit 
expeditions  to,  105;  recently 
emancipated  slaves  make  poor 
colonists,  108 ;  Abolitionist 
methods  of  discouraging  emi- 
gration to,  141, 172,  189;  slaves 
offered  freedom  on  condition 
of  returning  to,  169;  becomes 
chief  aim  of  Colonizationists, 
177;  runaway  slaves  request 
to  go  to,  182;  Massachusetts 
demands  that  freed  slaves  be 
sent  to,  185 ;  Key  on  number 
of  slaves  willing  to  go  to,  186 ; 
Finley  on  same,  188;  unwil- 
lingness of  negroes  to  go  to, 
191 ;  number  of  emancipated 
slaves  sent  to,  214;  Liberia 
and  the  slave  trade,  216-217 ;  a 


barrier  to  the  slave  trade,  217, 
221 ;  U.  S.  cooperates  with 
Colonization  Society  in  end- 
ing slave  trade  in,  223-224; 
Edward  Everett  on  influence 
of  Colonization  in  ending 
slave  trade,  224-225. 

Lincoln,  Abraham,  145. 

Louisiana  Colonization  Society, 
61,  122. 

McDonogh,  John,  61,  183 ;  be- 
quest to  Society,  63 ;  value  of 
his  slaves,  and  his  plans  for 
freeing  them,  168,  197. 

McLane,  R.  M.,  184. 

Madison,  James,  61,  62,  88. 

Manumission,  see  Emancipation. 

Marshall,  John,  61,  62,  87. 

Maryland,  House  of  Represen- 
tatives, on  slavery,  30;  Coloni- 
zation Society,  61 ;  legislative 
appropriation,  1831,  62-63;  at- 
titude of  legislature  toward 
society,  79;  effect  of  South- 
ampton Insurrection  in,  92; 
secession  of  Maryland  Coloni- 
zation Society  from  parent 
society,  95,  96-98;  excludes 
ardent  spirits  from  Cape 
Palmas,  98;  expeditions  sent 
out  from  Maryland,  98 ;  Mary- 
land Colonizationists  not  con- 
trolled by  slave  holders,  101 ; 
influence  in  bringing  about  re- 
organization of  the  society, 
115;  effect  of  abolitionist  op- 
position in,  160 ;  Gurley  on  the 
influence  of  the  colonization 
scheme  on  slaveholders  in 
Maryland,  170-171. 

Massachusetts,  41,  79,  80,  185. 

Meade,  Bishop  William,  34,  49, 

57,  58-59. 

Mercer,  C.  R,  16,  34,  54,  57,  61, 
75,  215-217. 

Methodist  Church,  163-166. 

Mills,  Samuel  J.,  42,  43,  52,  53. 

Mississippi,  Colonization  So- 
ciety, 61 ;  sentiment  in,  81 ;  ef- 
fect of  reorganization  of  par- 
ent society  upon  sentiment  in, 
122;  Methodist  Church  in,  165. 

Monroe,  James,  52,  55,  90,  188. 

New  England,  41,  77~78,  I37~ 
138. 


543] 


INDEX 


231 


New  Jersey,  79. 

New  Orleans,  160,  210. 

New  York,  79,  106,  no,  114-115, 

117,  120,  177. 
North  Carolina,  59,  188-189. 

Ohio,  61,  79,  81. 

Otis,  Harrison  Gray,  146. 

Page,  Mrs.  Ann  R.,  152-153. 

Paine,  Elijah,  60,  186. 

Panic  of  1837,  191. 

Pennsylvania,  80,  98,  114-115, 
163,  177- 

Perry,  M.  C,  220,  221-222. 

"  Pro-Slavery  Argument,"  10 ;  J. 
B.  Harrison's  reply,  II,  155- 
156;  attitude  of  American 
Colonization  Society  toward, 
ii ;  influence  of,  155,  156. 

Rhode  Island,  79. 

Roberts,    Governor,    of   Liberia, 

222. 

Sherman,  Roger  M.,  36,  161. 

Sierra  Leone,  40-41,  42,  52,  67. 

Slavery,  see  American  Coloniza- 
tion Society,  Emancipation, 
etc. 

Slave  Trade,  African,  11,  53-54, 
70,  177,  215-225. 

Smith,  Gerrit,  attitude  toward 
slaveholders  in  1828,  16;  on 
colonization,  32 ;  contributor 
to  American  Colonization  So- 
ciety, 60,  62;  on  the  constitu- 
tionality of  federal  aid  to  the 
society,  86 ;  attitude  of  Coloni- 
zation Society  toward  slavery, 
91 ;  opinion  of  Colonization 
Society,  140;  reason  for  de- 
serting the  Colonizationists, 
176. 

South  Carolina,  49,  81. 

Southwest,  effect  of  economic 
development  on  question  of 
slavery,  10-11,  155. 

Stiles,  Ezra,  39-40. 


Stockton,  Captain  R.  F.,  67,  68. 

Tappan,  Arthur,  90,  140,  178. 

Tazewell,  L.  W.,  86. 

Tennessee,  79. 

Thornton,  Dr.  William,  attitude 
toward  slaveholders,  15-16, 
21 ;  attitude  toward  slavery, 
28,  181 ;  efforts  to  colonize  the 
negro,  40-41 ;  and  the  Amer- 
ican Colonization  Society,  43- 
51 ;  and  the  slave  trade,  217. 

Tyler,  John,  61. 

Upsur,  Abel  P.,  61. 

Vermont,  79. 

Virginia,  legislative  committee 
proposes  colonization,  1777, 
40;  1800,  41-42;  Colonization 
Society  of,  61 ;  legislative  ap- 
propriation for  colonization, 
63 ;  attitude  of  legislature, 
1820-1830,  70,  82-84;  opposi- 
tion to  federal  aid  to  coloniza- 
tion, 82,  85-86,  87-88;  effect 
of  the  Southampton  Insurrec- 
tion on  sentiment  in,  92;  legis- 
lature not  representative  of 
the  State  on  question  of  sla- 
very, 93-94;  Virginia  Coloni- 
zationists not  controlled  by 
slaveholders,  101 ;  effect  of  re- 
organization of  the  American 
Colonization  Society  upon 
sentiment  in,  122;  attitude  of, 
toward  slavery,  158-160;  ef- 
fect of  abolitionist  opposition 
to  Colonization  in,  159,  160; 
constitutional  scruples  on  the 
subject  of  slavery,  159. 

Washington,  Bushrod,  46,  50. 
Webster,  Daniel,  221. 
Weld,  Theodore  D.,  178. 
Whittier,  J.  G.,  179. 
Whittlesey,  Elisha,  94,  117,  148. 
Wilberforce,  William,  35,  91. 
Wilkeson,  Samuel,  118-119,  I31- 


THE  OBLIGATION  OFCONTRACTS  CLAUSE  OF  THE 
UNITED  STATES  CONSTITUTION 


i'T? 

SERIES  XXXVII  NO.  4 

JOHNS  HOPKINS  UNIVERSITY  STUDIES 

IN 

HISTORICAL  AND  POLITICAL  SCIENCE 

Under  the  Direction  of  the 

Departments  of  History,  Political  Economy,  and 
Political  Science 


THE    OBLIGATION    OF     CONTRACTS 

CLAUSE  OF  THE  UNITED  STATES 

CONSTITUTION 


BY 

WARREN  B.  HUNTING,  PH.D. 
Late  Second  Lieutenant,  i68th  Infantry,  A.  E.  F. 


BALTIMORE 


1919 

- 


COPYRIGHT  1919  BY 
THE  JOHNS  HOPKINS  PRESS 


PRESS  OF 

THE  NEW  ERA  PRINTING  COMPANY 
LANCASTER,  PA. 


CONTENTS 


PREFACE  .... 
CHAPTER  I. 
CHAPTER  II. 

CHAPTER  III. 

CHAPTER  IV. 
CHAPTER  V. 


PAG* 

vii 


Introduction    1 1 

The  Meaning  of  "Obligation  of  Con- 
tracts "  Considered 15 

Can  a  State  Be  Obligated  by  a  Con- 
tract?   40 

The  Dartmouth  College  Case 58 

The  Obligation  of  Contracts  Clause  as 
Viewed  by  the  Framers  of  the  Con- 
stitution . .  .in 


PREFACE 

The  general  purpose  of  this  study  is  the  examination  of 
the  questions  which  have  been  decided  by  the  Supreme 
Court  of  the  United  States  in  cases  arising  under  that  clause 
of  Article  I,  section  10,  of  the  United  States  Constitution 
which  provides  that  "  no  States  shall  .  .  .  pass  any  law  im- 
pairing the  obligation  of  contracts"  (and  which  will,  for 
convenience,  be  referred  to,  hereafter,  as  the  "contracts 
clause"),  in  so  far  as  these  questions  relate,  in  any  way,  to 
special  privileges  granted  by  the  States.  By  "  special  privi- 
leges "  reference  is  had  to  what  are  commonly  known  as 
"  franchises,"  such  as  the  privilege  of  being  a  corporation, 
the  privileges  of  engaging  in  certain  public  service  busi- 
nesses such  as  that  of  common  carriage,  the  privilege  of  ex- 
ercising the  state's  power  of  eminent  domain,  the  privilege 
of  using  the  public  streets  and  highways  for  tracks,  pipes, 
wires,  etc. ;  and  also  to  those  privileges  which  may  be  dis- 
tinguished from  "  franchises  "  by  the  designation  of  "  im- 
munities," such  as  the  immunity  or  exemption  from  taxa- 
tion by  the  state,  or  from  rate  regulation.  This  use  of  these 
terms  is  adopted  because  it  calls  attention  to  an  important 
distinction  between  the  two  kinds  of  privileges.  The  usage 
is  not  universal,  however.  Blackstone  designates  all  spe- 
cial privileges  by  the  general  term  "  franchises." 

A  survey  of  the  decisions  will  show  that  the  questions 
arising  in  these  cases,  when  viewed  most  broadly,  divide 
themselves  into  two  rather  different  fields  of  inquiry.  The 
first  field  is  concerned  with  the  questions  which  are  peculiar 
to  the  "  contracts  clause,"  per  se — such  as,  What  is  a  "  con- 
tract"?— and  which  are  fundamental  to  a  true  understand- 
ing of  the  clause.  The  second  field  is  concerned  with  the 
construction  of  particular  grants  of  privileges.  Here  the 
leading  principle  is  the  so-called  doctrine  of  the  strict  con- 

vii 


Vlll  OBLIGATION   OF   CONTRACTS 

struction  (in  favor  of  the  state)  of  state  grants.  It  might 
be  described  as  the  general  law  of  franchises  and  immuni- 
ties, for  it  is  a  body  of  law  whose  characteristic  rules  are 
due,  not  to  the  "contracts  clause"  itself,  but  to  the  fact 
that  the  States  have  made  certain  peculiar  grants  or  con- 
tracts which,  because  they  have  been  made  by  States,  are 
regarded  and  construed  in  a  peculiar  way.  These  rules 
might  easily  have  arisen  had  there  been  no  "contracts 
clause  "  in  the  Constitution.  They  would  have  arisen  wher- 
ever franchises  are  regarded  as  legal  interests  to  be  pro- 
tected by  the  courts  from  infringement  by  the  Government, 
whether  under  the  "  due  process  of  law  clause "  or  some 
other  similar  constitutional  provision  or  the  ordinary  law 
of  the  land. 

In  the  first  of  the  two  fields  of  inquiry  which  we  have 
noted  it  has  been  the  especial  endeavor  to  arrive  at  a  true 
understanding  of  the  principal  conceptions  underlying  the 
"  contracts  clause  "  or,  at  least,  of  such  of  them  as  are  nec- 
essarily involved  in  a  consideration  of  the  contracts  of  the 
States.  This  part  of  the  study  will  include  an  examination 
of  the  much  criticised  Dartmouth  College  case  and  the 
hardly  less  criticised  case  of  Fletcher  v.  Peck,  with  the  pur- 
pose of  determining  the  justice  of  these  criticisms. 

In  the  second  field  the  special  endeavor  has  been  to  dis- 
cover the  proper  conception  of  the  doctrine  of  strict  con- 
struction, and  to  trace  the  application  of  that  doctrine  to  the 
details  of  the  various  particular  franchises  which  have  been 
the  subject  of  litigation  with  the  purpose  of  stating,  so  far 
as  possible,  what  the  cases  have  actually  decided,  of  testing 
the  correctness  of  the  application  of  the  doctrine  of  strict 
construction  to  particular  cases,  and  of  tracing  the  fluctua- 
tions, if  any  there  be,  in  the  general  attitude  of  the  court 
towards  this  doctrine.  This  can  be  done  the  better  inas- 
much as  the  Supreme  Court,  in  these  cases,  has  generally 
confined  itself  to  a  reference  to  its  own  precedents,  which 
thus  have  gradually  worked  themselves  out  into  a  more  or 
less  unified  body  of  law. 


PREFACE  IX 

A  more  detailed  explanation  of  the  field  covered  and  its 
relation  to  the  whole  subject  of  the  "  contracts  clause  "  will 
be  found  in  the  Introduction,  which  follows.  It  is  not 
thought  that  the  work  done  in  the  second  field  of  inquiry, 
because  it  is  confined  to  an  examination  of  the  decisions  of 
the  United  States  Supreme  Court  alone,  will  be  lacking  in 
practical  utility,  for  it  is  only  these  decisions  that  can  give 
an  authoritative  statement  of  the  law  of  franchises  and  im- 
munities as  it  will  be  applied  by  the  federal  courts  when 
their  aid  is  invoked  for  the  protection  of  these  grants,  and 
they  are  asked  to  apply  the  prohibitions  of  the  "contracts 
clause."  In  the  second  place,  although  the  State  courts  are 
not  bound  to  follow  the  decisions  of  the  Supreme  Court 
in  so  far  as  they  may  choose  to  give  a  greater  protection  to 
franchises,  either  by  applying  the  "contracts  clause"  or 
some  prohibition  of  the  State  constitution,  than  the  Supreme 
Court  has  seen  fit  to  do,  nevertheless  the  State  courts  do 
regard  the  decisions  of  the  Supreme  Court  in  this  class  of 
cases  with  very  great  respect,  and  will  generally  follow 
them.  Therefore  the  Supreme  Court  decisions  are  about 
the  best  source  from  which  to  discover  what  has  been 
termed  the  general  law  of  franchises  and  immunities;  and 
because  the  "  contracts  clause,"  under  the  Constitution  and 
the  provisions  of  the  United  States  statutes  as  to  the  judi- 
ciary, always  gives  the  Supreme  Court  jurisdiction  of  these 
cases  where  the  owner  of  the  franchise  is  dissatisfied  with 
the  decision  of  the  State  court,  a  great  many  of  them  have, 
naturally,  come  before  the  court,  thus  securing  a  compre- 
hensive and  more  or  less  unified  character  to  its  body  of 
decisions  on  this  subject. 

The  writer  wishes  to  express  his  sense  of  indebtedness  to 
Professor  W.  W.  Willoughby,  director  of  the  Department 
of  Political  Science  at  the  Johns  Hopkins  University,  be- 
cause it  was  through  him  that  he  was  led  to  undertake  this 
study,  and  more  especially  because  it  is  his  instruction  and 
friendly  counsel,  very  largely,  that  have  enabled  the  writer  to 


X  OBLIGATION   OF  CONTRACTS 

obtain  a  conception  of  the  methods  and  requirements  of 
legal  reasoning. 

W.  B.  H. 

Dr.  Hunting  was  killed  in  France  on  July  15,  1918,  while 
serving  in  the  American  army.  He  had  intended  to  add  to 
the  study  here  published  chapters  dealing  respectively  with 
"  Consideration,"  "  Franchises  under  the  Contracts  Clause," 
"Charters," "Special  Franchises," "Rate  Privileges,"  "Tax 
Exemptions,"  "  Effect  of  Sales,  Mortgage  Foreclosures,  Re- 
organizations, Consolidation  and  Merger  upon  Franchises," 
and  "  The  Effect  of  the  Reserved  Right  to  Alter,  Amend  or 
Repeal  upon  Charter  Franchises  and  Privileges."  Consid- 
erable progress  had  been  made  by  Dr.  Hunting  upon  these 
chapters,  but  the  manuscript  was  not  in  a  condition  that 
justified  its  publication. 


THE  OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS  CLAUSE 
OF  THE  UNITED  STATES  CONSTITUTION 


CHAPTER  I 
INTRODUCTION 

The  most  fundamental  of  the  questions  arising  out  of 
the  "  contracts  clause  "  are  obviously  these :  ( i )  What  is  a 
"contract"?  (2)  What  is  the  "obligation"  of  a  "con- 
tract"? (3)  What  is  a  "law"?  (4)  What  constitutes  an 
"impairment"?  A  general  view  of  the  cases  that  have 
arisen  under  this  clause  suggests  that  the  contracts  which 
are  sought  to  be  protected  under  it  may  profitably  be  classi- 
fied into  contracts  between  private  individuals,  that  is,  pri- 
vate contracts,  and  contracts  between  a  State  and  private 
individuals,  or  between  two  States,  that  is,  State  contracts. 
This  classification  is  justified  by  the  fact  that  the  two  kinds 
of  contracts,  generally  speaking,  do  not  both  raise  for  solu- 
tion the  same  fundamental  inquiries,  the  nature  of  which 
we  have  already  stated.  And  in  the  cases  where  they  do 
raise  the  same  fundamental  inquiry,  the  principle  for  deter- 
mining it  is  often  different  in  the  case  of  state  contracts 
-from  what  it  is  in  the  case  of  private  contracts. 

The  purpose  of  this  study  is  to  cover  those  contracts  of 
the  States  which  confer  special  privileges,  and  which  may 
be  designated  as  "  franchises  "  and  "  immunities,"  that  is  to 
say,  the  franchise  is  to  be  a  corporation,  and  franchises  to 
engage  in  public  services  such  as  railroad,  street  railway 
and  telegraph  franchises,  ferry  and  bridge  franchises,  water 
and  gas  franchises,  franchises  to  use  the  streets  of  a  city 
for  gas  and  water  pipes  and  street  railways,  and  finally,  be- 
cause they  are  of  somewhat  the  same  nature  as  these  fran- 

ii 


12  OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS  [5 $6 

chises,  rate  privileges  and  tax  exemptions.  This  study, 
therefore,  omits  from  the  field  of  state  contracts  those  cases 
which  have  dealt  with  contracts  contained  in  state  securi- 
ties— that  they  should  be  receivable  in  payment  of  taxes 
and  the  like, — land  grants  by  the  States,  and  cases  of  con- 
tracts between  the  States,  or  between  a  State  and  the  United 
States. 

The  first  question  to  be  considered  is  the  power  of  the 
States  to  obligate  themselves  by  contract.  This  involves 
first  a  consideration  of  the  meaning  of  the  terms  "obliga- 
tion "  and  "  contract,"  viewed  as  technical  legal  concepts, 
and  then  a  consideration  of  their  meaning  when  viewed  in 
the  light  of  the  circumstances  surrounding  the  adoption  of 
the  "contracts  clause."  It  involves  also  the  more  specific 
questions,  whether  a  grant  is  a  contract  and  whether  a  char- 
ter of  incorporation  is  a  contract.  It  will  then  be  consid- 
ered whether  or  not  a  consideration  is  required  for  the 
validity  of  the  contracts  of  the  States,  and  if  so,  what  con- 
stitutes a  consideration. 

As  the  obligation  of  a  contract,  generally  speaking,  has 
been  held  to  be  that  which  a  party  is  obligated  to  do,  accord- 
ing to  the  law  of  the  State  wherein  the  contract  was  made 
and  as  prescribed  by  that  law  at  the  time  the  contract  was 
so  made,  it  is  obvious  that  in  these  cases  the  federal  courts, 
when  they  seek  to  determine  what  the  obligation  of  a  par- 
ticular contract  is,  are  called  upon  to  determine  a  question 
of  state  law.  Moreover,  as  regards  contracts  made  by  the 
state  which  can,  of  course,  only  be  made  by  law,  as  the  state 
can  only  act  through  law,1  the  legislature  must  be  authorized 
by  the  state  constitution  to  make  the  contract,  and  must 
enter  into  a  contract  by  means  of  a  legislative  act,  and  any 
inferior  body  must  likewise  obtain  authority  from  the  legis- 
lature, before  it  can  enter  into  contracts  on  behalf  of  the 
state.  In  these  cases,  therefore,  the  federal  courts  not  only 
have  to  determine  a  question  of  state  law,  but  a  question  of 
state  constitutional  or  statutory  law.  Some  consideration, 

1 W.  W.  Willoughby,  The  Nature  of  the  State,  pp.  195,  221. 


557]  INTRODUCTION  1 3 

therefore,  is  necessary  of  the  relations  between  the  state 
and  federal  courts  in  cases  of  this  kind,  and  the  respect  paid 
by  the  federal  courts  to  the  decisions  of  the  state  courts-. 

The  obligation  of  a  contract  is,  of  course,  chiefly  deter- 
mined by  the  language  of  the  particular  contract  in  ques- 
tion, and  the  courts  must  necessarily  interpret  this  language 
for  themselves,  so  that,  in  many  cases,  perhaps  in  the 
greater  part  of  those  here  reviewed,  the  court  is  engaged 
simply  in  construing  the  language  of  particular  contracts. 
It  is  doing  what  any  state  court  might  have  to  do,  under  the 
ordinary  law  or  under  provisions  in  the  state  constitution, 
and  which  the  Supreme  Court  itself  might  have  had  to  do 
under  the  "  due  process  clause  "  of  the  federal  Constitution, 
as  well  as  under  the  "contracts  clause."  As  one  of  the 
parties  to  these  contracts  is  a  State,  however,  a  new  aspect 
is  put  upon  the  question ;  the  contract  is  no  longer  construed 
by  the  ordinary  rules ;  it  is  interpreted  in  the  light  of  a  spe- 
cial canon  of  construction  that  has  been  adopted  by  the 
courts,  namely,  that  all  such  contracts  are  to  be  construed 
strictly  against  the  grantee  and  in  favor  of  the  State.  The 
general  nature  of  this  doctrine  of  strict  construction  must 
therefore  be  considered,  and  this  will  be  followed  by  chap- 
ters upon  charters,  special  franchises,  rate  privileges  and 
tax  exemptions,  all  of  which  will  be  chiefly  taken  up  with 
tracing  the  application  of  this  doctrine  to  the  facts  of  par- 
ticular cases. 

The  effect  of  mortgage  foreclosures,  consolidations,  mer- 
gers, sales  and  reorganizations  of  corporations  is  included 
in  the  study,  first,  because  no  opinion  can  be  given  upon  the 
question  whether  a  corporation  has  or  has  not  the  privileges 
which  belonged  to  its  predecessor  corporation  unless  one  is 
familiar  with  the  peculiar  rules  of  law  applicable  to  these 
transactions;  secondly,  because  these  rules  very  largely  re- 
sult from  an  application  of  the  doctrine  of  strict  con- 
struction. 

The  subject  of  the  effect  of  the  reserved  right  to  alter, 
amend  or  repeal  charters,  franchises  and  immunities  is  also 


14  OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS  [558 

treated,  inasmuch  as  this  is  now  one  of  the  most  important 
phases  of  the  law  dealing  with  these  special  privileges.  It 
may  probably  be  said,  also,  that  the  cases  on  this  subject 
involve,  theoretically  at  any  rate,  an  application  of  the  pro- 
hibition of  the  "  contracts  clause." 

It  was  intended  to  add  chapters  dealing  with  the  police 
power  as  affecting  franchise  and  immunities,  with  the  ques- 
tion what  is  an  "  impairment,"  and  the  question  what  is  a 
"  law,"  but  these,  owing  to  lack  of  time  to  complete  them, 
have  been  omitted. 


CHAPTER  II 

THE  MEANING  OF  "OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS" 
CONSIDERED 

It  was  stated  in  the  preceding  chapter  that  the  questions 
arising  out  of  the  "  contracts  clause  "  might  be  analyzed,  in 
a  general  and  abstract  way,  into :  what  is  a  "  contract "  ? 
what  is  its  "  obligation  "  ?  what  is  a  "  law  "  ?  and  what  con- 
stitutes an  "impairment"?  Within  the  first  two  of  these 
inquiries  have  fallen  the  most  important  particular  questions 
which  have  arisen  over  the  "  contracts  clause  " — the  ques- 
tions which  have  aroused  the  most  discussion  and  have 
given  rise  to  the  most  celebrated  cases.  These  are :  whether 
a  grant  or  executed  contract  is  a  "  contract "  and  gives  rise 
to  an  "  obligation  " ;  whether  a  state  can  "  contract "  and  be 
under  an  "obligation"  thereby;  whether  a  charter  of  incor- 
poration can  be  said  to  be  a  "  contract " ;  whether  the  "  obli- 
gation of  contracts  "  is  derived  from  natural  or  from  posi- 
tive law — a  pertinent  question  in  determining  whether  the 
"obligation"  of  a  "  contract"  can  be  prospectively  impaired, 
or  only  retrospectively ;  finally,  whether  the  remedy  for  the 
enforcement  of  a  "  contract,"  which  is  in  force  at  the  time 
of  its  making,  is  a  part  of  the  "  obligation." 

The  last  of  these  questions  falls  rather  within  the  domain 
of  private  contracts,  or  contracts  between  individuals,  than 
within  the  domain  of  state  contracts,  and  so  does  not  espe- 
cially concern  us,  but  the  first  four  are  all  involved  in  a  con- 
sideration of  the  contracts  of  states,  and  therefore  demand 
our  attention.  Of  course,  these  questions  have  long  since 
been  answered  in  leading  cases  that  settle  the  law  upon  the 
points  involved.  A  review  of  the  first  eight  cases  decided 
by  the  court,  wherein  the  "contracts  clause"  was  applied, 
will  give  the  answers  to  the  questions  which  we  have  put. 

'5 


1 6  OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS  [560 

They  are  taken  in  their  chronological  order  so  as  to  show 
the  way  in  which  the  law  actually  developed. 

In  1810  in  Fletcher  v.  Peck,1  it  was  held  that  a  grant  of 
land  was  a  contract,  and  that  a  State  was  as  much  obligated 
by  its  grant  of  land  as  an  individual  by  his.  A  statute  re- 
pealing the  grant  was,  therefore,  held  to  impair  the  obliga- 
tion of  a  contract. 

In  1812  in  New  Jersey  v.  Wilson,2  it  was  held  that  an 
agreement  providing  for  exemption  from  taxation,  made 
with  the  Indians  by  the  State  of  New  Jersey  in  connection 
with  a  tract  of  land  granted  them  in  consideration  of  a  sur- 
render by  them  of  their  claims  to  other  tracts  of  land,  was 
a  contract  protected  by  the  "  contracts  clause." 

In  1819  in  the  case  of  Sturges  v.  Crowninshield,3  it  was 
held  that  a  state  bankruptcy  law  impaired  the  obligation  of 
contracts  which  had  been  made  prior  to  its  enactment.  It 
was  not  necessary  to  determine  whether  the  obligation  of 
the  contract  was  created  by  positive  or  by  natural  law. 

In  the  very  next  case,  however,  McMillan  v.  McNeill,4 
Marshall,  speaking  for  the  court,  did  hold  an  insolvent  law 
to  constitute  an  impairment  of  the  obligation  of  a  contract 
made  subsequent  to  its  enactment,  stating  that  the  case  could 
not  be  distinguished  from  that  of  Sturges  v.  Crowninshield. 
This  holding  of  Marshall's  was  later  explained  away,  upon 
the  ground  that  the  insolvent  law  there  involved  was  that 
of  Louisiana,  while  the  contract  was  made  in  South  Caro- 
lina, and  hence  was  not  subject  to  the  law  of  Louisiana  in 
so  far  as  its  essential  validity  and  its  obligation  were  con- 
cerned. 

In  the  same  year,  1819,  the  case  of  Trustees  of  Dart- 
mouth College  v.  Woodward5  was  decided.  This  case  held 
that  the  charter  incorporating  Dartmouth  College,  granted 
by  the  Crown  in  the  year  1769,  constituted  a  contract  with 


1 6  Cranch,  87. 

2  7  Cranch,  164. 

3  4  Wheat.  122. 

4  4  Wheat.  209 — 1819. 
8  4  Wheat.  518. 


561]          MEANING  OF  "OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS"  I/ 

the  English  state  the  obligation  of  which  passed  to  the  State 
of  New  Hampshire  upon  her  severance  from  England,  and 
came  under  the  protection  of  the  United  States  Constitution 
when  she  became  a  member  of  the  Union.  The  case  has 
always  been  regarded  as  establishing  the  doctrine  that  all 
charters  of  private  corporations  are  contracts. 

In  Owings  v.  Speed6  it  was  held  that  the  "  contracts 
clause  "  did  not  operate  to  invalidate  a  law  passed  prior  to 
the  going  into  effect  of  the  Constitution. 

In  Farmers'  and  Mechanics'  Bank  v.  Smith7  the  prin- 
ciple of  Sturges  v.  Crowninshield  was  reaffirmed. 

In  1823  in  Green  v.  Biddle8  it  was  held  that  a  contract 
between  two  of  the  States  of  the  Union  was  within  the  pro- 
tection of  the  "contracts  clause"  equally  with  a  contract 
between  two  individuals,  or  a  State  and  an  individual. 

In  1827  in  Ogden  v.  Saunders9  it  was  held  that  a  state 
insolvency  law  could  not  be  considered  as  operating  as  an 
impairment  of  the  obligation  of  contracts  entered  into  sub- 
sequently to  its  enactment.  The  majority  judges  delivered 
separate  opinions,  the  reasoning  of  which — each  judge  look- 
ing at  the  question  from  a  slightly  different  point  of  view — 
is  difficult  to  harmonize.  It  is  probably  true,  however,  that 
they  all  essentially  agreed  on  the  proposition  that  the  obli- 
gation of  a  contract  made  within  a  sovereign  state,  must  be 
precisely  that  allowed  by  the  law  of  the  state  and  none 
other.  This  case  contains  the  best  discussion  to  be  found 
in  the  reports  as  to  what  is  the  meaning  of  the  words  "  obli- 
gation "  and  "  contracts  "  as  found  in  the  Constitution. 

In  the  light  of  these  adjudications  it  might  seem  that 
further  discussion  of  these  questions  would  be  useless. 
However,  the  first  and  fifth  of  these  decisions,  particularly, 
have  been  very  much  criticised.  It  has  been  said  that  Chief 
Justice  Marshall  was  wrong  both  in  the  decision  that  a 
grant  was  a  contract  and  in  holding  that  a  charter  of 

•  5  Wheat.  420—1820. 
7  6  Wheat.  131—1821. 
s  8  Wheat.  I. 
9  12  Wheat.  213. 


1 8  OBLIGATION   OF  CONTRACTS  [562 

incorporation  was  a  contract;  that  the  first  decision  was 
made  in  a  friendly  suit,  manufactured  for  the  purpose  of 
obtaining  a  ruling;  and  that,  in  the  second,  the  court  was 
led  astray  by  the  persuasive  eloquence  of  Daniel  Webster, 
combined  with  the  weakness  of  the  opposing  counsel,  and 
the  employment  by  Webster  and  his  associates  of  influence 
other  than  that  of  argument  in  open  court.  It  has  also  been 
said  that  the  "contracts  clause"  was  never  intended  to 
apply  to  the  contracts  of  the  States.10 

Because  it  is  believed  that  it  is  a  matter  of  some  interest 
to  determine  whether  these  foundation  principles  of  our 
constitutional  jurisprudence  are  fundamentally  wrong  or 
not,  and  that  it  is  possibly  a  matter  of  present  importance, 
in  so  far  as  the  tendency  to  a  gradual  warping  away  from 
these  principles  is  increased,  if  the  belief  is  general  that  they 
were  wrongly  decided,  we  shall  undertake  an  examination 
of  the  ratio  decidendi  of  these  decisions  in  order  to  deter- 
mine the  justice  of  the  criticisms  which  have  been  made 
upon  them.  It  is  believed,  also,  that  such  an  examination 
will  bring  out  the  fundamental  conceptions  involved  in  this 
clause  more  clearly  than  it  is  possible  to  do  in  any  other  way. 

For  the  purposes  of  the  following  discussion  we  shall 

10  The  most  elaborate  criticism  of  the  Dartmouth  College  Case  is 
to  be  found  in  John  M.  Shirley's  "  The  Dartmouth  College  Causes," 
a  book  devoted  exclusively  to  that  purpose.  The  number  of  critics 
is  swelled,  however,  by  such  writers  as  the  late  Chief  Justice  Doe 
of  New  Hampshire,  writing  in  6  Harvard  Law  Rev.  161,  213;  Clem- 
ent H.  Hill  in  8  Am.  Law  Rev.  198  (perhaps  the  strongest  criticism 
that  has  been  made)  ;  and  numerous  others,  among  which  may  be 
mentioned  the  anonymous  writer  in  28  Am.  Law  Rev.  440;  J.  F. 
Orton  in  the  Independent,  Aug.  19  and  26,  1909;  J.  P.  Cotton,  Jr.,  in 
his  edition  of  Marshall's  decisions.  On  p.  347  Cotton  says :  "  One 
rises  from  the  opinion  dissatisfied — there  is  bias  in  the  statement  of 
facts,  bias  in  the  statement  of  premises,  and  the  assumption  that  the 
charter  was  a  contract  is  too  hasty  and  too  barely  supported."  Ad- 
verse judgments  are  expressed  by  Prof.  Jeremiah  Smith  in  John 
Marshall,  ed.  by  Dillon,  vol.  i,  pp.  154-155,  370;  by  Morawetz  in  his 
work  on  Corporations,  2d  ed.,  sec.  1045,  p.  1005.  Henry  Cabot  Lodge, 
in  his  life  of  Daniel  Webster,  expresses  the  opinion  that  the  decision 
was  due  to  Webster's  skillful  presentation  of  the  political  aspects  of 
the  case  so  as  to  arouse  within  Marshall  a  belief  that  the  principles 
of  Federalism  were  menaced.  See,  to  the  same  effect,  28  Am.  Law 
Rev.  356. 


563]          MEANING  OF  "OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS"  1 9 

need  to  premise  only  two  or  three  of  the  ordinary  rules  of 
statutory  and  constitutional  construction  which,  we  assume, 
any  person  who  endeavors  to  ascertain  the  true  meaning  of 
the  "  contracts  clause  "  would  have  to  follow,  namely :  that 
the  words  and  phrases  of  the  clause  should  be  given  their 
ordinary  meaning;  that  since  it  is  quite  apparent  that  the 
clause  is  dealing  with  a  technical,  legal  subject  matter,  its 
terms  should  be  interpreted  in  the  light  of  their  technical 
or  legal  meaning,  which  would  be,  presumptively,  the  mean- 
ing given  to  them  by  the  common  law ;  finally,  that  the  court 
must  look  to  the  general  opinion  current  at  the  time  of  the 
adoption  of  the  Constitution,  and  at  all  facts  and  circum- 
stances shedding  light  on  that  opinion,  in  order  to  determine 
whether  the  technical  meaning  of  the  language  used  should 
be  either  restricted  or  enlarged. 

With  this  preface,  we  shall  begin  with  the  first  question 
that  was  presented  to  the  court,  that  is,  whether  a  grant  was 
a  "contract"  with  an  "obligation"  within  the  meaning  of 
the  "  contracts  clause." 

Is  a  Grant  a  Contract? 

In  answering  this  question  we  must  consider,  to  some  ex- 
tent, what  was  meant  by  "contracts"  and  what  was  con- 
sidered to  be  their  "  obligation."  And  perhaps  the  best  way 
to  approach  the  subject  is  by  considering  the  views  of  mod- 
ern jurists  as  to  the  conceptions  included  in  these  terms. 

First,  as  to  obligation :  this  term  originated  in  the  Roman 
law,  and  was  a  fundamental  conception  of  that  law,  as  it 
has  been  and  still  is  of  the  civil  law.  The  excellent  expla- 
nation given  by  Salmond  is  quoted  in  the  notes,  where  it 
may  be  referred  to,11  but  for  our  present  purpose  his  short 

11  Salmond,  Jurisprudence,  sec.  165,  p.  428:  "Obligation,  in  its 
popular  sense  is  merely  a  synonym  for  duty.  Its  legal  sense,  derived 
from  Roman  law,  differs  from  this  in  several  respects.  In  the  first 
place,  obligations  are  merely  one  class  of  duties,  namely  those  which 
are  the  correlatives  of  rights  in  personam.  An  obligation  is  the 
vinculum  juris,  or  bond  of  legal  necessity  which  binds  together  two 
or  more  determinate  individuals.  It  includes,  for  example,  the  duty 
to  pay  a  debt,  to  perform  a  contract,  or  to  pay  damages  for  a  tort 


2O  OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS  [564 

definition  is  sufficient.  He  says :  "  An  obligation,  therefore, 
may  be  defined  as  a  proprietary  right  in  personam  or  a  duty 
which  corresponds  to  such  a  right."  Disregarding  the 
qualification  of  "proprietary"  which  is  immaterial  to  our 
present  purpose,  it  will  be  noted  that  an  obligation  is  a  legal 
relationship  between  two  persons,  involving  a  right  on  one 
side  and  a  duty  on  the  other  (though  the  duty  is  often  the 
only  part  of  the  relation  referred  to  as  the  "obligation"), 
and  that  this  duty  is  one  in  personam,  that  is,  it  is  a  particu- 
lar duty  owed  to  the  other  party  to  the  relationship,  such  as 
a  promise  to  pay  money,  and  is  contradistinguished  from  a 
common  duty  which  all  alike  owe,  such  as  the  duty  of  re- 
fraining from  interfering  with  a  person's  rights  over  the 
property  which  he  owns.  The  obligation,  being  a  legal  rela- 
tionship, is  necessarily  a  creature  of  law.  Of  course  cer- 
tain acts  are  the  occasions  of  the  arising  of  obligations,  but 
such  acts  cannot  truly  be  said  to  create  them.12  This  con- 
ception is  that  which  modern  jurists,  equally  with  the  jurists 
of  Rome,  attribute  to  the  term  obligation. 

As  to  contract:  Savigny  defined  a  contract  as  "the  con- 
currence of  several  persons  in  a  declaration  of  intention 
whereby  their  legal  relations  are  determined."13  Accord- 
ing to  this  definition,  it  will  be  noticed,  a  conveyance  would 
constitute  a  contract  since,  in  a  conveyance,  the  legal  rela- 
tions of  the  two  parties  are  determined  by  a  concurrence  of 
the  wills  of  the  parties ;  and  it  is  for  this  reason  that  Markby 
criticises  Savigny's  definition,14  claiming  that  he  thereby 
loses  sight  of  the  fundamental  distinction  between  a  con- 
veyance and  a  contract,  which  Austin  so  laboriously  insisted 

but  not  the  duty  to  refrain  from  interference  with  the  person,  prop- 
erty or  reputation  of  others.  Secondly,  the  term  obligation  is  in 
law  the  name  not  merely  of  the  duty  but  also  of  the  correlative 
right.  .  .  .  Thirdly,  and  lastly,  all  obligations  pertain  to  the  sphere 
of  proprietary  rights.  ...  An  obligation  therefore  may  be  defined 
as  a  proprietary  right  in  personam  or  a  duty  which  corresponds  to 
such  a  right." 

12  Markby,  Elements  of  Law,  sec.  603,  p.  298. 

18  Savigny,  Treatise  on  Roman  Law,  2d  French  ed.,  Paris,  1856, 
vol.  iii,  p.  314;  see  also  Markby,  sec.  608. 

14  Markby,  sees.  609-610. 


565]          MEANING  OF  "OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS"  21 

upon.  He  thinks  it  unimpeachable  as  a  definition  of  "agree- 
ment," but  would  limit  the  term  contract  to  those  agree- 
ments which  involve  a  promise  to  do  or  forbear  from  some 
future  act.  In  other  words,  he  would  limit  the  idea  of 
contract  to  agreements  by  which  obligations  are  occasioned 
between  the  parties.  The  dispute  is,  to  a  certain  extent, 
one  of  nomenclature,  for  Savigny  made  a  division  of  con- 
tracts into  two  classes,  obligatory  and  not  obligatory.  What 
Markby  calls  a  contract,  he  calls  an  "  obligatory  contract," 
that  is,  a  contract  which  occasions  an  obligation  between  the 
parties.15  Savigny's  conception  of  an  obligatory  contract 
is  that  which  most  of  the  English  jurists  term  a  contract. 
Thus  Anson  says :  "  Contract  is  that  form  of  agreement 
which  directly  contemplates  and  creates  an  obligation."16 
According  to  Salmond,  "  A  contract  is  an  agreement  which 
creates  an  obligation  or  right  in  personam  between  the  par- 
ties."17 When  Pollock  says,  "a  contract  is  an  agreement 
and  promise  enforceable  by  law,"18  the  idea  that  the  agree- 
ment contemplates  and  effects  an  obligation  is  conveyed  by 
the  added  words  "and  promise."  Salmond  criticises  this 
definition  on  the  ground  that  certain  agreements  occasion 
legal  relations  which  may  be  termed  contracts,  although  they 
are  not  enforceable,  for  example,  voidable  and  illegal  con- 
tracts— but  into  this  question  it  is  not  necessary  to  enter. 
Holland  accepts  Savigny's  wide  use  of  the  word  contract, 
distinguishing,  however,  between  the  wider  and  narrower 
senses  of  the  term.19 

It  is,  therefore,  clear  that,  although  these  jurists  differ 
upon  the  question  whether  or  not  a  conveyance  should  prop- 

16  Savigny.  See,  for  example,  p.  317,  where  he  says :  "  If  one  mis- 
conceives the  contractual  nature  of  these  numerous  and  important 
acts,  it  is  because  he  fails  to  distinguish  from  them  the  obligatory 
contract  which  ordinarily  precedes  and  accompanies  them.  Thus, 
for  example,  in  the  sale  of  a  house,  attention  is  called,  and  rightly, 
to  the  obligatory  contract  of  sale,  but  it  is  forgotten  that  the  subse- 
quent '  tradition '  is  a  contract  at  the  same  time  entirely  apart  from 
this  sale,  although  necessitated  by  it." 

16  Anson,  Contracts,  nth  ed.,  p.  2. 

1T  Salmond,  sec.  123,  p.  313. 

18  Pollock,  Contracts,  p.  2. 

19  Holland,  Jurisprudence,  loth  ed.,  pp.  209,  249. 


22  OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS  [566 

erly  be  termed  a  contract,  they  all  agree  that  a  conveyance, 
whether  contract  or  not,  does  not  give  rise  to  any  obligation. 
The  English  jurists,  indeed,  have  laid  great  stress  upon  the 
point.  Austin  insisted  upon  the  distinction  with  his  char- 
acteristic vigor,  and  Markby,  Holland  and  Salmond  have  all 
followed  him.  So  also  have  Anson  and  Pollock  in  their 
authoritative  treatises  on  the  law  of  contracts.  Anson 
says,  speaking  of  agreements,  and  meaning  thereby  a  con- 
currence of  the  will  of  two  or  more  persons  whereby  their 
legal  relations  are  determined:  "But  agreement  as  thus 
defined  seems  to  be  a  wider  term  than  contract.  It  includes 
legal  transactions  of  two  kinds  besides  those  which  we  ordi- 
narily term  contracts.  These  are:  (i)  Agreements  the 
effect  of  which  is  concluded  so  soon  as  the  parties  thereto 
have  expressed  their  common  consent  in  such  manner  as  the 
law  requires.  Such  are  conveyances  and  gifts  wherein  the 
agreement  of  the  parties  at  once  effects  a  transfer  of  rights 
in  rem,  and  leaves  no  obligation  subsisting  between  them."20 
Sir  Frederick  Pollock  expresses  the  same  idea  when  he 
says:  "A  consideration,  properly  speaking,  can  be  given 
only  for  a  promise.  Where  performance  on  both  sides  is 
simultaneous,  there  may  be  agreement  in  the  wider  sense, 
but  there  is  no  obligation  and  no  contract."21 

The  manner  in  which  this  result  is  reached  will  clearly 
appear  if  we  glance  over  the  fundamental  doctrines  which 
these  jurists  propound.  The  content  of  a  legal  right  is  "a 
capacity  residing  in  one  man  of  controlling  .  .  .  the  actions 
of  others."  This  capacity  is  given  by  the  state  to  the  pos- 
sessor of  the  right.  The  state  is  the  creator  and  recognizer 
of  rights.  And  this  is  the  principle  upon  which  it  creates 
or  recognizes  rights  or  the  transference  of  them:  "The 
origination,  transfer  and  extinction  of  rights  .  .  .  are  due 
to  Facts,  i.e.,  either  an  Event  or  an  Act."22  A  Juristic  Act 
is  defined  as  "a  manifestation  of  the  will  of  a  private 

20  Anson  on  Contracts,  p.  3. 

21  Pollock  on  Contracts,  7t'h  Eng.  ed.,  p.  167.    See  also  Holland, 
.pp.  248-249. 

22  Holland,  p.  151. 


567]  MEANING  OF  "OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS"  23 

individual  directed  to  the  origin,  termination  or  altera- 
tion of  rights."23  Another  name  for  Juristic  Act,  and  one 
which  shows  its  nature  very  clearly,  is  Act  in  the  Law. 
Further,  "  Juristic  Acts  are  distinguished  into  '  one-sided/ 
where  the  will  of  only  one  party  is  active,  as  in  making  a 
will,  accepting  an  inheritance,  or  taking  seisin;  and  'two- 
sided,'  where  there  is  a  concurrence  of  two  or  more  wills  to 
produce  the  effect  of  the  act,  which  is  thus  a  '  contract '  in 
the  widest  sense  of  that  term."24  In  other  words,  the 
theory  seems  to  be  that  rights  are  created  and  transferred, 
but  always  by  the  state.  The  state  takes  cognizance  of  cer- 
tain phenomena,  upon  the  appearance  of  which  it  declares 
rights  to  exist  or  to  inhere  in  certain  persons.  A  contract 
or  agreement  between  two  persons  is  simply  one  of  these 
phenomena.  When  "A"  enters  into  an  agreement  whereby 
he  gives  his  chattels  or  his  land  to  "  B  "  and  agrees  that 
"  B  "  shall  have  them,  "B"  acquires  rights  in  the  transferred 
property,  not  because  "  A  "  gave  them  to  him,  but  because 
the  law  declares  that  he  shall  have  them.  The  law  termi- 
nates "  A 's  "  rights  and  originates  "  B's."25  There  is  no 
obligation,  no  subsisting  legal  relation  arising  out  of  the 
transaction.26 

This  analysis  of  the  operation  and  effect  of  a  conveyance 
seems  strange,  at  first  glance,  because  of  the  extent  to  which 
it  minimizes  the  part  played  by  the  grantor  in  the  transac- 
tion. One  naturally  feels  that  the  grantee  acquires  his 
right  because  the  grantor  gives  it  to  him.  In  other  words, 
the  grantor  had  a  right  to  possess  and  control  the  thing; 
he  had  a  right,  likewise,  to  give  it  away.  Yet,  if  one  pushes 
the  analysis  a  little  farther  along  this  line,  he  might  without 
much  difficulty  arrive  at  the  conclusion  that  the  absolute 

23  Ibid.,  p.  112. 

24  Ibid.,  p.  118. 

25  Ibid.,  p.  153. 

26  It  is  difficult  to  understand  what  Holland  means  by  the  follow- 
ing note,  which  is  found  on  page  153 :  "  Puchta,  Inst.  II,  p.  325, 
points  out  that  in  all  derivative  acquisitions  there  is  a  legal  relation 
between  the  auctor  and  the  person  acquiring;  not  merely  a  loss  by 
one  and  a  gain  to  another  as  in  usucapio." 


24  OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS  [568 

owner  and  possessor  of  a  right  can  not  really  divest  himself 
of  it,  but  that  the  most  he  can  do  is  to  agree  to  allow  another 
person  to  exercise  possession  and  control  over  the  thing, 
and  to  agree  not  thereafter  to  assert  his  own  rights,  as 
against  such  person.  We  would  say,  however,  that  we  do 
not  believe  that  the  natural,  or  ordinary,  practical  view  of 
the  transaction — which  we  have  already  vouched  as  author- 
ity for  questioning  the  view  that  the  whole  force  of  a  con- 
veyance is  derived  from  the  law  alone — would  reach  to  the 
other  logical  extreme  of  holding  that  the  donor's  power  is 
so  absolute  that  he  cannot  divest  himself  of  it.  The  prac- 
tical view  would  rather  be,  it  seems  to  us,  that  the  grantee 
derives  his  right  from  the  consent  of  the  grantor,  and  yet 
that,  once  the  grantor  has  completed  the  formalities  evi- 
dencing that  consent,  all  his  right  and  power  has  become 
extinguished,  and  he  is  not,  therefore,  under  any  further 
and  subsisting  obligation  towards  his  grantee. 

Turning  next  to  Fletcher  v.  Peck,  it  is  noticeable  that  both 
Chief  Justice  Marshall,  delivering  the  opinion  of  the  major- 
ity of  the  court,  and  Justice  Johnson,  dissenting,  adopt  the 
general  conception,  which  we  have  heretofore  given,  of  the 
term  obligation.  It  is  only  when  they  come  to  apply  that 
conception  to  the  case  of  a  conveyance  that  they  are  unable 
to  agree.  What  we  have  termed  the  practical  view,  and 
what  is,  when  elaborated  and  fitted  into  a  system,  the  view 
of  the  modern  jurists,  was  stated  very  clearly,  in  that  case, 
by  Justice  Johnson  in  his  dissenting  opinion.  He  said: 

Whether  the  words  "acts  impairing  the  obligation  of  contracts" 
can  be  construed  to  have  the  same  force  as  must  have  been  given  to 
the  words  obligation  and  effect  of  contracts  is  the  difficulty  in  my 
mind. 

There  can  be  no  solid  objection  to  adopting  the  definition  of  the 
word  "  contract "  given  by  Blackstone.  The  etymology,  the  classical 
signification  and  the  civil  law  idea  of  the  word  will  all  support  it. 
But  the  difficulty  arises  on  the  word  "obligation"  which  certainly 
imports  an  existing  moral  or  physical  necessity.  Now  a  grant  or 
conveyance  by  no  means  necessarily  implies  the  continuance  of  an 
obligation  beyond  the  moment  of  executing  if.  It  is  most  generally 
but  the  consummation  of  a  contract,  is  functus  officio  the  moment  it 
is  executed,  and  continues  afterwards  to  be  nothing  more  than  the 
evidence  that  a  certain  act  was  done.27 

27  6  Cranch  78,  144. 


569]          MEANING  OF  "OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS"  25 

Marshall  answered  the  argument  in  this  manner: 

A  contract  is  a  compact  between  two  or  more  persons  and  is  either 
executory  or  executed.  An  executory  contract  is  one  in  which  a 
party  binds  himself  to  do,  or  not  to  do,  a  particular  thing,  such  was 
the  law  under  which  the  conveyance  was  made  by  the  governor.  A 
contract  executed  is  one  in  which  the  object  of  contract  is  per- 
formed, and  this,  says  Blackstone,  differs  in  nothing  from  a  grant. 
The  contract  between  Georgia  and  the  purchasers  was  executed  by 
the  grant.  A  grant,  in  its  own  nature,  amounts  to  an  extinguish- 
ment of  the  right  of  the  grantor,  and  implies  a  contract  not  to  reas- 
sert that  right.  A  party  is,  therefore,  always  estopped  by  his  own 
grant. 

Since  then,  in  fact,  a  grant  is  a  contract  executed,  the  obligation 
of  which  still  continues,  and  since  the  constitution  uses  the  general 
term  contract  without  distinguishing  between  those  which  are  exec- 
utory and  those  which  are  executed,  it  must  be  construed  to  com- 
prehend the  latter  as  well  as  the  former.  A  law  annulling  convey- 
ances between  individuals  and  declaring  that  the  grantors  should 
stand  seized  of  their  former  estates,  notwithstanding  those  grants, 
would  be  as  repugnant  to  the  constitution  as  a  law  discharging  the 
vendors  of  property  from  the  obligation  of  executing  their  con- 
tracts by  conveyances.  It  would  be  strange  if  a  contract  to  convey 
was  secured  by  the  Constitution,  while  an  absolute  conveyance  re- 
mained unprotected.28 

Thus  Marshall  gave  to  the  word  obligation  the  general 
meaning  which,  we  have  seen,  Roman,  civilian,  and  modern 
jurists  all  attribute  to  it.  He  recognized  it  essentially  as 
"a  tie,  whereby  one  person  is  bound  to  perform  some  act 
for  the  benefit  of  another,"29  He  sought  to  point  out  what 
it  was  that  the  grantor  in  a  conveyance  was  still  bound  to 
do,  or  rather  to  refrain  from  doing,  after  the  act  of  convey- 
ance had  been  performed.  Was  he  correct,  then,  in  saying 
that  every  grant  implies  a  contract  not  to  reassert  the  right 
which  has  been  granted  ? 

When  we  ask,  Was  he  correct?  we  mean,  Was  he  justi- 
fied by  authority?  And  the  first  authority  to  which  we 
shall  turn  will  be  the  writers  upon  the  general  jurisprudence 
of  that  time.  It  seems  to  us  that  it  must  be  borne  in  mind, 
in  any  consideration  of  the  early  cases  construing  the  "  con- 
tracts clause,"  that  the  phrase  "obligation  of  contracts" 
was  foreign  to  the  common  law,  but  that  it  was  a  term  and 
conception  in  general  use  in  the  Roman  and  civil  law  and 

28  6  Cranch,  78,  136. 

29  This  is  the  definition  of  Holland,  p.  236. 


26  OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS 

in  the  so-called  law  of  nature;  and,  finally,  that  the  prin- 
ciples of  this  law  of  nature  constituted  the  generally  ac- 
cepted philosophy  of  law  of  that  day.30 

It  is  a  reasonable  presumption  that  the  writers  upon  nat- 
ural law  would  tend  to  regard  a  conveyance  of  property  as 
a  contract.  In  developing  a  theory  of  property,  these  jur- 
ists usually  started  with  some  such  general  proposition  as 
that  all  things  were  originally  owned  in  common.  This 
gave  each  man  a  natural  and  inherent  right  in  the  world's 
wealth.  The  general  mass  of  property  was  then  usually 
regarded  as  having  been  divided  up  by  an  agreement  or 
contract  between  every  one,  each  renouncing  his  right  in 
the  property  which  was  thereafter  to  be  owned  in  severalty 
by  each  of  the  others.  This  plainly  partakes  of  the  nature 
of  an  obligatory  contract.  The  more  so  because,  philo- 
sophically viewed,  one  can  not,  of  his  own  act,  totally  divest 
himself  of  a  right  which  is  absolutely  his.  And,  in  any 
event,  the  one  and  only  element  of  the  conveyance,  accord- 
ing to  natural  law,  was  the  consent  of  the  parties.  Or,  if 
they  started  with  the  premise  that  no  man  had  any  right  of 
property  at  all,  they  then  derived  the  right  of  property 
from  a  general  contract  whereby  each  agreed  not  to  inter- 
fere with  the  enjoyment  of  the  others  in  the  specific  pieces 
so  allotted  to  each.  Here,  also,  is  plainly  an  obligatory  con- 

80  How  generally  accepted  it  was  we  shall  show  in  more  detail 
hereafter.  We  shall  also  show  that  Marshall  accepted  the  doctrine, 
and  that  his  construction  of  the  "  contracts  clause "  was  always 
based  upon  this  "natural  law"  conception  of  obligation  and  con- 
tract. It  will  hardly  be  disputed  that,  in  deciding  Fletcher  v.  Peck, 
it  would  have  been  quite  proper  to  have  adverted  to  the  writers 
upon  natural  law  to  see  what  light  they  were  able  to  shed  upon  the 
question  whether  or  not  a  conveyance  was  a  contract  and  involved 
a  subsisting  obligation.  The  arguments  in  Fletcher  v.  Peck  are  not 
reported.  It  was  not  the  custom  then,  we  believe,  to  file  printed 
briefs.  Arguments  were  confined  to  those  made  orally  in  court,  of 
which  the  judges  took  notes.  Although,  therefore,  it  is  not  certain 
that  civil  or  natural  law  precedents  were  referred  to  in  that  case,  it 
is  extremely  probable  that  such  was  the  fact,  in  view  of  the  emi- 
nence of  the  counsel — J.  Q.  Adams  and  Joseph  Story  on  one  side 
and  Luther  Martin  on  the  other — and  in  view  of  a  reference  to  civil 
law  doctrines  which  Justice  Johnson  made  in  his  dissenting  opinion. 


57 1 ]          MEANING  OF  "OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS"  2/ 

tract.     The  transferring   of   the   right,  thereafter,   would 
seem  to  partake  of  much  the  same  nature. 

In  confirmation  of  the  foregoing  statements  regarding 
the  views  of  the  writers  upon  natural  law,  we  may  cite 
Pufendorf.  This  writer  holds  that  certain  obligations  are, 
by  the  law  of  nature,  born  with  men;  but  that  all  other 
obligations,  which  he  terms  "  adventitious "  obligations, 
"  proceed  from  a  simple,  or  from  a  mutual  act,  of  which 
the  former  is  properly  called  a  free  grant  or  promise,  the 
latter  a  pact  or  covenant."  Regarding  promises  and  pacts 
or  covenants,  he  says  :31 

But  inasmuch  as  all  acknowledge  that  promises  and  pacts  do  trans- 
fer a  right  to  others,  before  we  proceed,  it  may  not  be  improper  to 
examine  Hobbes's  opinion  about  the  transferring  of  right.  He 
then,  from  his  project  of  a  state  of  nature,  having  inferred,  that 
every  man  hath  naturally  a  right  to  everything,  and  having  farther 
shown,  that  from  the  exercise  of  the  right  there  must  needs  arise  a 
war  of  every  man  against  every  man,  a  state  very  unfit  for  the  pres- 
ervation of  mankind,  he  concludes,  "  That  whilst  reason  commands 
men  to  pass  out  of  this  state  of  war,  into  a  condition  of  peace, 
which  peace  is  consistent  with  a  right  of  every  man  to  every  thing, 
it  at  the  same  time  prescribes  that  men  should  lay  down  some  part 
of  this  universal  right."  "A  man,"  he  says,  "may  lay  down,  or  divest 
himself,  of  his  right  in  two  ways,  either  by  simply  renouncing  it, 
or  by  transferring  it  to  another.  The  former  is  done,  if  he  declares 
by  sufficient  signs,  that  he  is  content  it  shall  hereafter  be  unlawful 
for  him  to  do  a  certain  thing,  which  before  he  might  have  lawfully 
done.  The  latter  if  he  declare  by  sufficient  signs  to  another  person, 
who  is  willing  to  receive  such  a  right  from  him,  that  he  consents 
it  shall  be  for  the  future,  as  unlawful  for  himself  to  resist  him  in 
the  doing  of  a  certain  thing,  as  he  might  before  have  justly  resisted 
him."  Hence  he  infers  that  the  transferring  of  right  consists  purely 
in  non-resistance;  or  that,  he  who  in  a  state  of  nature  transfers  a 
right  to  another  does  not  give  the  other  party  a  new  right  which 
before  he  wanted,  but  only  abandons  his  own  right  of  resisting  such 
a  person  in  the  exercise  of  his. 

Pufendorf  takes  issue  with  this  explanation  to  this  ex- 
tent. He  maintains  that  in  a  state  of  nature  man  has 
powers  only  and  not  rights,  "  for  'tis  ridiculous  trifling  to 
call  that  power  a  right,  which  should  we  attempt  to  exer- 

81  Pufendorf,  Law  of  Nature  and  Nations,  with  notes  by  Bar- 
beyrac,  translated  by  Kennett,  4th  ed.,  1729;  Book  3,  chap,  v,  sees. 
i  and  2,  p.  259.  - 


28  OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS  [$72 

cise,  all  other  men  have  an  equal  right  to  obstruct  or  pre- 
vent us."    He  then  continues  :82 

Thus  much  then  we  allow,  that  every  man  has  naturally  a  power 
or  license  of  applying  to  his  use,  any  thing  that  is  destitute  of  sense 
or  reason.  But  we  deny  that  this  power  can  be  called  a  right,  both 
because  there  is  not  inherent  in  those  creatures  any  obligation  to 
yield  themselves  unto  man's  service ;  and  likewise  because  men  being 
naturally  equal,  one  cannot  fairly  exclude  the  rest  from  possessing 
any  such  advantages  unless  by  their  consent,  either  express  or  pre- 
sumptive, he  has  obtained  the  peculiar  and  sole  enjoyment  of  it. 
...  A  man  then  acquires  an  original  right  over  things,  when  all 
others  either  expressly  or  tacitly  renounce  their  liberty  of  using 
such  a  thing,  which  before  they  enjoyed  in  common  with  him.  This 
original  right  being  once  established,  by  virtue  of  which  the  primi- 
tive community  of  things  was  taken  off,  the  transferring  of  right 
is  nothing  else  but  the  passing  it  away  from  one  to  another,  who 
before  was  not  master  of  it.  Hence  appears  the  absurdity  of  saying, 
that  the  transferring  of  right  consists  barely  in  non-resistance.  In- 
asmuch as  that  negative  term  cannot  express  the  force  of  the  obliga- 
tion arising  from  such  an  act;3&  which  properly  implies  an  inward 
inclination  to  make  good  the  contract.  Though  non-resistance  be 
indeed  one  consequence  of  the  obligation,  and  without  which  it  can- 
not be  fulfilled.  .  .  .  He  [Hobbes]  ought  indeed  to  have  expressed 
himself  thus:  Since  in  a  state  of  mere  nature  things  belonged  no 
more  to  one  than  to  another,  therefore  if  a  particular  person  desired 
the  sole  use  of  anything,  to  make  him  master  of  his  wish,  it  was 
necessary  that  all  other  men  should  renounce  the  use  of  the  same 
thing.  If  they  did  this  gratis,  the  act  had  somewhat  in  it  like  a 
gift;  if  with  some  burden,  or  under  some  condition,  it  was  then 
a  kind  of  contract,  for  which  we  have  no  name.  But  should  one 
man  have  renounced  his  power  over  such  a  thing,  this  could  have 
been  no  prejudice  to  others,  and  consequently  he  only  would  have 
been  debarred  from  the  use  of  it,  who  had  thus  freely  quitted  all 
title  to  it. 

It  would  seem  correct  to  say  that  both  Pufendorf  and 
Hobbes  regarded  a  conveyance  as  essentially  a  contract  with 
a  subsisting  obligation.  Hobbes'  "  renunciation  "  is  clearly 
a  contract,  and  Pufendorf's  chief  objection  is  that  Hobbes 
makes  the  "  obligation  "  of  the  transaction  merely  a  passive 
one.  It  being  established  that  an  obligation  arises  out  of 
the  transaction,  the  fact  that  Pufendorf  calls  those  convey- 
ances which  are  made  gratis  gifts,  and  those  made  with  a 
burden  or  condition  contracts,  is  of  little  moment.  This  is 
simply  due  to  his  peculiar  use  of  the  word  "  contracts."  All 
alienation,  he  elsewhere  states,  is  effected  through  the  coti- 

82  Ibid.,  pp.  260-261. 
33  Italics  ours. 


573]          MEANING  OF  "  OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS  "  29 

currence  of  the  will  of  both  the  grantor  and  the  grantee,84 
which  is  a  pact.  In  the  ordinary  acceptation  of  the  term 
this  would  be  a  contract.  It  would  clearly  be  a  contract  at 
common  law,  whose  broad  definition  of  contract,  waiving 
the  requirement  of  consideration,  was:  "An  agreement  of 
two  or  more  persons  to  do  or  not  to  do  a  particular  thing."35 
Pufendorf's  distinction  between  pacts  and  contracts  was 
certainly  not  the  generally  accepted  one  among  writers  upon 
the  law  of  nature.  Barbeyrac  says  that  he  derived  it  from 
some  of  the  Roman  law  authorities.86 

Kent,37  in  his  commentaries,  writing  in  the  year  1827, 
says: 

There  has  been  much  discussion  among  the  writers  on  the  civil 
law,  whether  a  gift  was  not  properly  a  contract,  inasmuch  as  it  is 
not  perfect  without  delivery  and  acceptance,  which  imply  a  conven- 
tion between  the  parties.  In  the  opinion  of  Toullier  every  gift  is  a 
contract,  for  it  is  founded  on  agreement,  while  on  the  other  hand 
Pufendorf  had  excluded  it  from  the  class  of  contracts  out  of  defer- 
erence  to  the  Roman  lawyers,  who  restrained  the  definition  of  a 
contract  to  engagements  resulting  from  negotiation.  Barbeyrac,  in 
his  notes  to  Pufendorf,  insists  that,  upon  principles  of  natural  law, 
a  gift  inter  vivos,  and  which  ordinarily  is  expressed  by  the  simple 
term  gift,  is  a  true  contract,  for  the  donor  irrevocably  divests  him- 
self of  the  right  to  a  thing  and  transfers  it  gratuitously  to  another, 
who  accepts  it,  and  which  acceptance,  he  rationally  contends,  to  be 
necessary  to  the  validity  of  the  transfer.  The  English  law  does  not 

"Pufendorf,  Book  4,  chap,  ix,  sec.  i,  p.  413:  "Now  as  the  con- 
veyance of  rights  is  transacted  between  two  parties,  the  one  from 
whom,  and  the  other  to  whom  they  pass,  so  in  those  methods  of 
acquisition  which  flow  from  the  force  and  virtue  of  property  the 
concurrence  of  two  wills  is  required,  the  giver's  and  the  receiver's." 

85  2  Kent's  Corns.  450;  2  Blackstone's  Corns.  442. 

36  See  Pufendorf,  Book  5,  chap,  i,  sec.  4,  p.  473,  and  Barbeyrac's 
note  i  to  Book  5,  chap,  iv,  sec.  i,  p.  80.    Pufendorf  says :  "  In  my 
opinion  the  difference  between  pact  and  contract  may  be  best  taken 
from  the  object,  so  as  to  call  that  contract  which  concerns  those 
things  and  actions  which  are  the  subject  of  traffic  and  so  presuppose 
property  and   price;   and  that  pact  by  which  we  covenant  about 
other  things.    By  this  means  pact,  strictly  speaking,  will  take  in  all 
negative  agreements,  by  which  we  covenant  not  to  do,  or  not  to 
demand,  what  otherwise  we  might  do  or  demand;  as  also  those 
agreements  that  have  for  their  object  the  exercise  of  our  natural 
faculties,  so  far  as  they  hereby  tend  to  the  promoting  of  mutual 
profit  and  advantage,  considered  merely  by  themselves  without  any 
regard  to  price,  or  any  valuable  consideration,  in  a  word,  when  we 
agree  to  do  some  work  that  is  not  mercenary." 

37  2  Kent's  Corns.  438. 


3O  OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS  [574 

consider  a  gift,  strictly  speaking,  in  the  light  of  a  contract,  because 
it  is  voluntary  and  without  consideration,  whereas  a  contract  is 
denned  to  be  an  agreement  upon  sufficient  consideration  to  do  or 
not  to  do  a  particular  thing. 

Although  called  "  civil  law  "  writers,  Puf endorf  and  Bar- 
beyrac  were,  as  we  have  seen,  writers  on  the  law  of  nature, 
and  it  was  in  treating  of  the  law  of  nature  that  they  dis- 
cussed the  nature  of  the  transfer  of  rights.  Pufendorf,  we 
have  further  seen,  seems  to  attribute  to  a  conveyance  all  the 
elements  of  a  contract  except  the  name,  and  particularly 
that  element  which  Chancellor  Kent  does  not  take  into  con- 
sideration at  all,  that  element  which  was  specifically  re- 
quired if  the  contract  was  to  come  within  the  operation  of 
the  "contracts  clause,"  namely,  the  element  of  obligation. 
Toullier  on  the  other  hand,  was  apparently  a  writer  on  the 
civil  law  in  the  strict  sense,  and  to  the  discussion  of  the 
civil  law  doctrines,  which  follows,  he  may,  therefore,  be 
added,  upon  the  authority  of  Kent,  as  a  writer  who  held 
that  a  conveyance  was  a  contract.  Austin  in  his  Lectures 
on  Jurisprudence,  and  particularly  in  several  of  the  notes 
that  have  been  appended  to  them,  discoursed  at  some  length 
upon  the  theories  of  contract  and  conveyance  held  by  the 
writers  on  the  civil  law,  and  it  is  upon  this  explanation  of 
the  civil  law  that  our  discussion  will  be  based. 

The  civil  law's  manner  of  dealing  with  this  question  was 
very  unsatisfactory  to  Austin's  logical  mind,  and  he  criti- 
cised it  with  much  vigor.  The  civil  law  doctrine  may  be 
summarized  in  the  language  of  Amos.38  After  describing 
the  ceremonies  of  tradition  and  mancipation,  he  continues : 

Most  of  the  acts  above  exemplified,  and  the  kinds  of  intentional 
transfer  they  represent,  follow  upon  previous  mutual  promises  and 
arrangements  between  the  old  and  the  new  owner.  This  has  led  to 
an  erroneous  notion  which  has  deeply  coloured  the  history  of  Roman 
law  in  the  Middle  Ages,  and  which  reappears  in  most  European 
Codes,  to  the  effect  that  all  rights  of  ownership  whatever  are  of 
necessity  preceded  by  a  contract,  or  at  least  an  obligation  arising 
put  of  a  contract  or  a  delict,  and  that  a  contract  has  for  its  main, 
if  not  its  only,  purpose  the  bringing  about  the  acquisition  of  rights 
of  ownership.  The  falsity  and  mischievousness  of  this  notion  has 
been  exhibited  in  great  detail,  and  with  much  assiduity  by  Mr. 
Austin. 

38  Amos,  Jurisprudence,  pp.  164-166. 


5/5]          MEANING  OF  "  OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS  "  3! 

Turning  now  to  Austin  himself,  we  find  this  comment 
upon  a  passage  from  the  famous  jurist  Heineccius : 

If  you  examine  this  passage  closely,  and  take  its  parts  in  conjunc- 
tion, you  will  find  it  involving  the  following  assumptions:  I.  That 
every  acquisition  of  dominium  consists  of  two  degrees :  One  of  them 
being  the  proximate ;  the  other  the  remote  cause  of  the  right.  One 
of  them,  modus  acquirendi  (strictly  so  called)  ;  the  other  titulus,  or 
titulus  ad  acquirendum.  2.  That  the  titulus,  or  remote  cause  of  the 
right,  ahvays  consists  of  an  incident  importing  jus  in  personam, 
e.g.  a  contract'. 

And  as  to  the  doctrine  of  the  Roman  lawyers,  he  said  that 
it  seemed  to  be  this : 

This  tradition  is  not  sufficient  to  pass  an  irrevocable  right,  unless 
the  preceding  contract  bind  the  alienor,  and  therefore  impart  to  the 
alienee  jus  ad  rem.  In  other  words,  the  tradition  is  not  sufficient  to 
pass  the  right  irrevocably,  unless  the  preceding  contract  amount  to 
Justus  titulus:  titulus  ad  transferendum  dominium  habilis.  Accord- 
ingly every  acquisition  by  delivery,  made  in  pursuance  of  a  contract', 
is  divisible  into  two  degrees:  a  mode  of  acquisition  and  a  title  to 
acquire.39 

If,  then,  an  obligatory  contract  was  a  necessary  part  of 
every  conveyance,  it  would  seem  to  follow  that  the  transfer 
of  the  rights  was  to  a  certain  extent  due  to  this  personal 
obligation,  so  that  every  conveyance  would  involve  a  con- 
tinuing obligation  of  a  kind.  And  the  French  code,  there- 
fore, said  of  a  sale,  where  no  tradition  was  necessary,  but 
where  title  passed  immediately,  that  the  dominium  was 
transferred  by  virtue  of  the  obligation  of  the  contract.40 

As  to  the  English  law,  it  is,  of  course,  extremely  difficult 
to  say  what  was  the  general  view  of  the  common  law  upon 
a  question  such  as  this.  Professor  Ames  and  Professor 

39  Austin,  Jurisprudence,  pp.  995,  996,  999.    Heineccius'  work  was 
published  in  1789. 

40  Austin's  comment  on  the  language  of  the  code  is  interesting. 
He  says :  "  to  style  the  sale  a  contract,  is  a  gross  solecism.    It'  is 
however  a  solecism  which  may  be  imputed  to  the  Roman  lawyers; 
and  with  which  it  were  not  candid  to  reproach  the  authors  of  the 
Code.    But  when  they  talk  of  obligations  as  imparting  dominium 
or  property,  they  talk  with  absurdity  which  has  no  example,  and 
which  no   example  could  extenuate.    If  they  had   understood  the 
system  which  they  so  servilely  adored  and  copied,  they  would  have 
known  that  obligation  excluded  the  idea  of  dominium:  that  it  im- 
parts to  the  obligee  jus  in  personam,  and  jus  in  personam  merely. 
This  is  its  essential  difference :  This  is  the  very  property  which  gives 
it  its  being  and  its  name."    Jurisprudence,  p.  1005. 


32  OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS  [576 

Maitland  have  shown  that  the  early  law  could  not  conceive 
of  the  transfer  of  rights  as  such.  Their  only  conception 
was  of  the  transfer  of  tangible  things.  A  conveyance, 
therefore,  according  to  Professor  Ames,  consisted  of  a 
transfer  of  the  seizin  or  possession  of  the  thing  granted  and 
an  abandonment  or  extinguishment  of  the  grantor's  right 
in  the  thing.  Thus  Professor  Ames  says : 

A  derivative  title  is  commonly  acquired  from  an  owner  by  pur- 
chase or  descent.  The  title  in  such  cases  is  said  to  pass  by  transfer. 
For  all  practical  purposes  this  is  a  just  expression.  But  if  the  trans- 
action be  closely  scrutinized,  the  physical  res  is  the  only  thing  trans>- 
ferred.  The  seller's  right  of  possession,  being  a  relation  between 
himself  and  the  res,  is  purely  personal  to  him,  and  cannot,  in  the 
nature  of  things,  be  transferred  to  another.  The  purchaser  may 
and  does  acquire  a  similar  and  coextensive  right  of  possession,  but 
not  the  same  right  that  the  seller  had.  What  really  takes  place  is 
this:  the  seller  transfers  the  res  and  abandons  or  extinguishes  his 
right  of  possession.  The  buyer's  possession  is  thus  unqualified  by 
the  existence  of  any  right  of  possession  in  another,  and  he,  like 
the  occupant,  and  for  the  same  reason,  becomes  absolute  owner.41 

And  again  he  says : 

Even  a  relation  between  a  person  and  a  physical  thing  in  his  pos- 
session, as  already  stated,  cannot  be  transferred.  The  thing  itself 
may  be  transferred,  and,  by  consent  of  the  parties  to  such  transfer, 
the  relation  between  the  transf error  and  the  thing  may  be  destroyed 
and  replaced  by  a  new  but  similar  relation  between  the  transferee 
and  the  res.*2 

This  view  of  the  transaction  is  further  supported  by  re- 
ferring to  the  old  form  of  conveyance  of  the  right  of  a  dis- 
seized owner  to  his  disseizor.  The  disseized  owner's  right 
constituted  what  was  left  of  ownership  after  it  had  been 
bereft  of  seizin,  and  it  gives  some  idea  of  the  nature  of  an 
ordinary  conveyance  when  it  is  pointed  out  that  this  con- 
veyance, or  release,  as  it  was  called  at  common  law,  was 
in  its  early  form  a  "quit-claim"  deed.43  And  the  phrase 
"quit-claim"  long  retained  its  place  in  the  conveyancing 
practice. 

41  Select  Essays  in  Anglo-American  Legal  History,  vol.  iii,  p.  564. 

42  Ibid.,  pp.  482-483 ;  and  see  the  statements  of  Maitland  in  his 
essay  on  the  Mystery  of  Seisin,  pp.  601-602. 

48  Speaking  of  the  forms  of  early  releases,  Holdsworth  says: 
"  Sometimes  the  party  swore  to  abide  by  the  transaction."  History 
of  English  Law,  vol.  iii,  p.  197. 


577]  MEANING  OF  "OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS"  33 

It  is  interesting  to  place  along  side  of  these  theories  of 
early  law  the  statement  of  Blackstone  as  to  the  nature  of 
gifts  of  chattels  personal,  as  showing  the  persistence  of 
ideas  in  the  field  of  law.  He  says:  "Grants  or  gifts  of 
chattels  personal  are  the  act  of  transferring  the  right  and 
the  possession  of  them;  whereby  one  man  renounces,  and 
another  immediately  acquires,  all  title  and  interest  therein."44 

Now  the  theory  stated  by  Professor  Ames  as  the  one  on 
which  the  early  law  acted,  that  a  gift  was  a  transfer  of  pos- 
session together  with  a  renunciation  of  right,  when  viewed 
philosophically  would  tend  to  lead  to  the  conclusion  that  a 
conveyance  involved  a  contract  with  a  subsisting  obligation. 
But  it  does  not  necessarily  follow  that  the  early  law  took 
this  further  step  and  more  philosophical  view.  It  would  be 
mere  theorizing  to  try  to  proceed  any  further  than  Pro- 
fessor Ames  has  himself  gone.  It  may  be  noted  that  the 
quit  claim  deed  generally  contained  words  of  grant  as  well, 
and  that  soon  the  phrases  in  common  use  were  that  the 
grantor  would  quit-claim  "his  right"  or  even  "the  land" 
to  the  grantee.45  And  according  to  Blackstone,  repeating 
Littleton  and  Coke,  a  release  from  a  disseized  owner  oper- 
ated by  way  of  passing  the  right  (mitter  le  droit)*9  It  is 
not  certain,  therefore,  that  the  common  law  did  regard  a 
conveyance  in  the  light  of  a  contract  with  a  subsisting  obli- 
gation. Nor  do  we  think  that  the  rule  that  a  person  is 
always  estopped  by  his  own  grant  affords  much  evidence 
that  there  was  an  obligation  and  a  contract  involved  in  a 
conveyance,  for  this  doctrine  was  only  used  when  a  person 
had  made  a  deed  of  property  which  he  could  not  then  con- 
vey, but  which  he  had  afterwards  become  the  owner  of. 
The  deed  therefor  could  have  had  no  operation  as  a  con- 
veyance, but  was  given  effect  as  an  estoppel.47 

We  do  not  find,  however,  writers  of  weight  classifying 

44  2  Blackstone's  Corns.,  p.  421. 

45  2  Pollock  &  Maitland,  History  of  English  Law,  p.  91. 

46  2  Blackstone's  Corns.,  p.  325. 

47  2  Blackstone's  Corns.,  ed.  Wendell,  p.  290,  note. 

3 


34  OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS 

conveyances  under  contracts.  Thus  there  is  the  statement 
of  Blackstone,  that  contracts  are  executory  or  executed  and 
that  a  contract  executed  differs  nothing  from  a  grant  ;*8  and 
a  statement  by  his  successor  in  the  Vinerian  Professorship 
to  the  effect  that :  "  Particular  goods  and  chattels  may 
change  their  owner  by  gift  or  grant  and  by  contract.  These 
I  mention  together  because,  as  Sir  William  Blackstone  ob- 
serves, even  a  gratuitous  gift  is  not  perfected  but  by  deliv- 
ery, and  consequently,  as  I  understand  it,  by  the  acceptance 
of  the  person  to  whom  the  goods  are  given,  which  has  the 
semblance  of  a  contract."49  And  we  would  point  out  that, 
call  a  conveyance  a  contract,  and  you  raise  the  suggestion 
that  there  must  be  an  obligation;  you  emphasize  the  fact 
that  the  grantee  has  his  rights  merely  by  the  consent  of  the 
grantor;  you  obscure  the  part  which  the  state  takes  in  the 
matter;  you  suggest  the  idea  that  if  one  man  obtains  his 
right  solely  from  another,  he  necessarily  holds  it  subject  to 
the  will  of  the  latter,  who  can  go  no  farther  than  to  bind 
himself  never  to  exercise  the  power  of  revocation. 

Finally  there  was  the  plain  statement  of  Powell  on  Con- 
tracts, a  work  published  in  1790,  and  written  by  a  person 
evidently  familiar  with  the  civil  law,  that  a  conveyance  in- 
volved a  contract  with  an  obligation.  It  was  this  work  that 
Justice  Washington  relied  upon,  in  his  opinion  in  the  Dart- 
mouth College  case.80 

48  2  Blackstone' s  Corns.,  p.  440  ff. 

49  2  Wooddeson,  Lectures,  n.  410. 

50  After  giving  a  definition  of  contract  as  found  in  Blackstone, 
and  one  from  the  civil  law,  Powell  says,  pp.  4-5 :  "  Perhaps  the  fol- 
lowing description  will  be  deemed  more  simple  than   either.    'A 
contract  is  a  transaction  in  which  each  party  comes  under  an  obli- 
gation to  the  other,  and  each,  reciprocally,  acquires  a  right  to  what 
is  promised  by  the  other.'    It  is  evident  that,  under  these  definitions 
of  a  contract,  every  feoffment,  gift,  grant,  lease,  loan,  pledge,  bar- 
gain, covenant',  agreement,  promise,  etc.,  may  be  included;   for  in 
all  these  transactions,  there  is  a  mutual  consent  of  the  minds  of  the 
parties  concerned  in  them,  upon  agreement  between  them,  respecting 
some  property  or  right  that  is  the  object  of  stipulation.    The  ingre- 
dients requisite  to  form  a  contract  are :  First,  Parties ;   Secondly, 
Consent;    Thirdly,   an   Obligation   to   be   constituted   or   dissolved. 
That  these  things  must  coincide  is  evident  from  the  very  nature  and 
essence  of  a  contract;  for  the  regular  effect  of  all  contracts  being 


579]          MEANING  OF  "OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS"  35 

The  English  writers  leaned  strongly  in  the  same  direc- 
tion. And,  in  spite  of  the  opinion  of  Austin  that  it  is  an 
absurdity  to  say  that  the  Roman  law  regarded  an  obligation 
as  imparting  dominium,  it  seems  to  us  that  when  it  was  said 
that  tradition  alone  was  not  sufficient  to  pass  an  irrevocable 
right  if  there  was  not  a  preceding  contract  binding  the 
alienor,  the  obligation  of  such  precedent  contract  is  an 
essential  part  of  the  conveyance,  and  may  be  said  to  be  sub- 
sistent  in  every  conveyance,  even  though  it  is  not,  of  itself, 
sufficient  to  effect  the  transfer  of  rights  in  rem.5* 

And,  finally,  we  would  point  out  that  a  distinction  might 
be  drawn  between  a  conveyance  by  an  individual  and  a  con- 
veyance or  grant  by  the  state,  and  that  the  latter  might  be 
regarded  as  more  in  the  nature  of  a  contract  than  the 
former,  inasmuch  as  the  state  has  the  power  to  disregard 
its  own  grants. 

As  to  the  English  law  on  this  point,  it  is  difficult  to  say 
what  was  the  theory  about  Crown  grants.  It  is  true  that 
Buller,  J.  said,  in  The  King  v.  Passmore,52  that  "  the  grant 
of  incorporation  is  a  compact  between  the  crown  and  a  num- 
ber of  persons,  the  latter  of  whom  undertake,  in  considera- 
tion of  the  privilege  bestowed,  to  exert  themselves  for  the 
good  government  of  the  place.  If  they  fail  to  perform  it, 
there  is  an  end  of  the  compact."  The  question  in  the  case 

on  one  side  to  acquire,  and  on  the  other  to  part  with,  or  alien  some 
property,  or  to  abridge  and  restrain  natural  liberty  by  binding  the 
parties,  or  one  of  them  to  do,  or  restraining  them  or  one  of  them, 
from  doing  something  which  before  he  might  have  done  or  omitted 
doing  at  his  pleasure,  it  is  necessary  that  the  party  to  be  bound, 
shall  have  given  his  free  assent  to  what  is  imposed  upon  him." 

51  As  to  the  true  theory  of  the  matter,  we  are  not  able  to  refute 
the  arguments  of  the  modern  jurists  we  have  referred  to.  Their 
contentions  seem  unanswerable.  And  if  their  view  is  the  correct 
one,  it  would  seem  much  better  not  to  speak  of  conveyances  as  con- 
tracts in  any  sense.  The  term  contract  distinctly  suggests  the  idea 
of  obligation.  Possibly  the  writers  who  use  it  do  see  some  sort  of 
obligation  in  a  conveyance.  We  have  already  noted  the  reference 
by  Holland  to  Putchta's  opinion  "  that  in  all  derivative  acquisitions 
there  is  a  legal  relation  between  the  auctor  and  the  person  acquiring ; 
not  merely  a  loss  by  one  and  a  gain  to  another,  as  in  usucapio." 
Holland,  p.  153.  What  else  can  such  a  relationship  be  but  a  right 
in  Personam  with  its  corresponding  duty? 

«  3  T.  R.  246. 


36  OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS 

was,  however,  over  the  duties  of  the  incorporators  who 
clearly  had  entered  into  an  obligatory  contract.  Speaking 
of  franchises,  Blackstone  said:  "But  the  same  identical 
franchise  that  has  been  granted  to  one  cannot  be  bestowed 
on  another,  for  that  would  prejudice  the  former  grant." 
Nevertheless,  the  authorities  which  he  cites  do  not  offer  any 
special  suggestion  of  the  contract  as  opposed  to  the  con- 
veyance theory.63  And  also,  as  to  the  doctrine  that  the  king 
cannot  repeal  a  charter  once  granted,  the  leading  case  of  The 
King  v.  Amery  does  not  disclose  any  particular  theory  of 
contract.6* 

Whether  it  was  because,  being  a  believer  in  the  general 
doctrines  of  natural  rights  and  natural  law,  he  considered 
that  all  conveyances  were  in  the  nature  of  contracts,  or 
whether  it  was  a  distinction  based  upon  the  nature  of  state 
grants,  we  find  that  James  Wilson,  the  reputed  author  of 
the  "contracts  clause,"55  in  an  argument  made  in  1785,  con- 
tended that  whenever  the  state  passes  a  law  granting  land, 

63  The  two  authorities  are  as  follows:  Keilway,  196  (1688)  :  "To 
which  the  court  responded  and  said,  that  if  the  King,  by  his  letters 
patent  dated  May  ist  grant  me  an  office,  or  other  things;  and  then  by 
other  patents  dated  May  2nd  he  grants  the  same  thing  to  a  stranger, 
these  second  patents  are  merely  void,  and  moreover,  I  will  have  a 
scire  facias  against  the  second  patentee  and  will  avoid  these  last 
patent  by  judgment  of  the  court."  2  Rolle,  Abr.  191  (1668) :  "If 
the  King  grant  two  several  letters  patent  of  the  same  thing,  the  first 
patentee  can  have  a  scire  facias  against  the  later  patentee  to  repeal 
the  later  patent." 

B*3  T.  R.  515;  at  568,  the  court  say:  "The  third  and  last  question 
will  then  be,  what  is  the  effect  of  the  subsequent  charter  of  restora- 
tion by  King  James  the  Second?  And  as  to  that  we  are  of  opinion 
that  it  was  a  void  charter,  and  of  no  effect.  For  though  it  be  com- 
petent to  the  Crown  to  pardon  a  forfeiture  and  to  grant  restitution, 
that  can  only  be  done  where  things  remain  in  statu  quo,  but  not  so 
as  to  affect  legal  rights  properly  vested  in  third  persons,  which  is  the 
case  here;  for  Charles  the  Second  whilst  the  forfeiture  existed  had 
incorporated  a  new  body  of  men  in  the  town,  and  invested  them 
with  new  rights ;  which  being  done,  it  would  not  have  been  in  the 
power  of  Charles  the  Second,  and  of  course  it  was  not  within  the 
power  of  his  successors,  to  defeat  an  interest  once  legally  vested  in 
such  new  corporation ;  and  there  cannot  exist  in  the  same  place  two 
independent  corporations  with  general  powers  of  government,  and 
therefore  we  think  that  such  charter  of  restoration  was  absolutely 
void  and  of  no  effect." 

65  See  the  argument  of  Hunter  in  Sturges  v.  Crowninshield,  4 
Wheat.  122. 


58i] 


MEANING  OF  "OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS"  37 


or  granting  charters  of  incorporation  or  other  privileges  of 
that  nature,  such  laws  are  to  be  considered  as  compacts. 
This  argument  was  made  in  opposition  to  certain  legislation 
then  pending  in  the  Legislature  of  Pennsylvania,  the  pur- 
pose of  which  was  to  repeal  the  charter  of  the  Bank  of 
North  America,  which  had  been  granted  by  a  preceding 
legislature.  Among  his  reasons  for  opposing  the  legisla- 
tion was  the  following: 

Because  such  a  proceeding  would  wound  that  confidence  in  the 
engagements  of  government,  which  it  is  so  much  the  interest  and 
duty  of  every  state  to  encourage  and  reward.  The  act  in  question 
formed  a  charter  of  compact  between  the  legislature  of  this  state, 
and  the  president,  directors  and  company  of  the  Bank  of  North 
America.  The  latter  asked  for  nothing  but  what  was  proper  and 
reasonable:  the  former  granted  nothing  but  what  was  proper  and 
reasonable;  the  terms  of  the  compact  were,  therefore,  fair  and 
honest;  while  these  terms  are  observed  on  one  side,  the  compact 
cannot,  consistently  with  the  rules  of  good  faith,  be  departed  from 
on  the  other.56 

Again,  after  stating  that  in  most  cases  it  is  true  that  a  state 
must  have  the  power  to  amend  and  repeal  its  own  laws,  he 
continues : 

Very  different  is  the  case  with  regard  to  a  law  by  which  the  state 
grants  privileges  to  a  congregation  or  other  society.  Here  two  par- 
ties are  instituted,  and  two  distinct  interests  subsist.  Rules  of  jus- 
tice, of  faith,  and  of  honor,  must,  therefore,  be  established  between 
them:  for  if  interest  alone  is  to  be  viewed,  the  congregation  or 
society  must  always  lie  at  the  mercy  of  the  community. 

Still  more  different  is  the  case  with  regard  to  a  law  by  which  an 
estate  is  vested  or  confirmed  in  an  individual;  if,  in  this  case,  the 
legislature  may,  at  discretion,  and  without  any  reason  assigned, 
divest  and  destroy  his  estate,  then  a  person,  seized  of  an  estate  in 
fee  simple,  under  legislative  sanction,  is,  in  truth,  nothing  more 
than  a  solemn  tenant  at  will. 

For  these  reasons,  whenever  the  objects  and  makers  of  an  instru- 
ment, passed  under  the  form  of  a  law,  are  not  the  same,  it  is  to  be 
considered  as  a  compact  and  interpreted  according  to  the  rules  and 
maxims  by  which  compacts  are  governed.57 

56  i  Wilson's  Works,  ed.  Andrews,  p.  565. 

57  Wilson  held  a  doctrine  of  obligation  which  may  be  epitomized 
in  the  following  sentences  taken  from  the  law  lectures  which  he 
published  in  1792.    After  stating  Pufendorf's  doctrine  "that  obliga- 
tions are  laid  on  human  beings  by  a  superior,"  he  continues :  "  To 
different  minds  the  same  things,  sometimes,  appear  in  a  very  differ- 
ent manner.    If  I  was  to  make  a  maxim  upon  this  subject,  it1  would 
be  precisely  the  reverse  of  the  maxim  of  Baron  Pufendorf.    Instead 


38  OBLIGATION  OF   CONTRACTS  [582 

If  it  erred  at  all,  we  think  the  summary  heretofore  made 
of  the  authority  which  Marshall  had  for  his  ruling  that  a 
grant  was  essentially  a  contract,  erred  because  it  stated  the 
case  too  weakly. 

In  discussing  the  question  whether  a  conveyance  is  a  con- 
tract, it  was  not  clearly  determined  whether  the  "obliga- 
tion "  of  a  contract,  as  that  term  is  used  in  the  Constitution, 
referred  to  the  obligation  created  by  positive  law,  or  to 
some  other  obligation — say  that  created  by  natural  law. 
Nor  was  it  necessary  to  do  so  in  order  to  pass  judgment 
upon  the  point.  For  if  the  obligation  was  that  created  by 
positive  law,  the  Roman,  civil  and  common  law  authorities 
which  we  have  cited  were  clearly  in  point,  and  the  doctrines 
of  natural  law  would  still  have  had  a  bearing  on  the  ques- 
tion, not  as  being  absolute  authorities,  but  as  having  some 
persuasive  force.  If,  on  the  other  hand,  the  term  "  obli- 
gation," as  we  suggested,  was  intended  to  have  reference  to 
what  may  be  called  the  "natural  law"  obligation  of  con- 

of  saying  that  a  man  cannot  obligate  himself ;  I  would  say,  that  no 
other  person  on  earth  can  oblige  him,  but  that  he  certainly  can  oblige 
himself.  Consent  is  the  sole  principle,  on  which  any  claim  in  conse- 
quence of  human  authority,  can  be  made  upon  one  man  by  another 
.  .  .  exclusively  of  the  duties  required  by  the  law  of  nature,  I  can 
conceive  of  no  claim,  that  one  man  can  make  on  another  but  in 
consequence  of  his  own  consent."  Wilson's  Works,  ed.  Andrews, 
p.  190.  As  we  have  been  quoting  freely  from  Pufendorf  to  show 
the  contractual  nature  of  a  conveyance,  upon  the  principles  of  nat- 
ural law,  and  as  the  doctrines  attributed  to  him  by  Wilson,  in  the 
above  quotation,  suggest  a  theory  of  analytical  rather  than  natural 
jurisprudence,  we  would  make  the  following  explanation  of  the 
apparent  discrepancy.  Pufendorf  did  state  the  doctrine  thus  attrib- 
uted to  him.  At  the  same  time  he  regarded  consent  as  constitutive 
of  obligations :  The  law  of  nature  is  sanctioned  by  the  command  of 
God.  Book  2,  chap,  viii,  sec.  20.  By  the  law  of  nature  certain  obli- 
gations are  born  with  men,  others,  which  he  calls  "  adventitious," 
"  fall  upon  men  by  the  intervention  of  some  human  deed,  not  with- 
out the  consent  of  the  parties.  .  .  .  When  men  have  engaged  them- 
selves by  pacts  their  nature  obliges  them  as  sociable  creatures,  most 
religiously  to  observe  and  perform  them."  Book  3,  chap,  iv,  sec.  3. 
The  state  is  founded  upon  the  social  and  governmental  compacts. 
Book  7,  chap,  ii,  sees.  6,  7,  8.  Civil  law  does  not  abrogate  natural 
law.  Indeed  he  says  that,  when  mankind  entered  into  the  social 
compact,  "  we  must  suppose  that  they  took  it  for  granted  that  nothing 
should  be  established  by  the  civil  law  which  was  contrary  to  the 
natural." 


583]          MEANING  OF  "OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS"  39 

tracts,  then  the  writers  upon  natural  law  could  be  consid- 
ered as  furnishing  the  best  authority  to  be  had. 

It  becomes  necessary  now,  however,  to  determine  more 
carefully  by  what  law  the  obligation  spoken  of  in  the  Con- 
stitution is  to  be  determined.  By  the  term  "  obligation  "  as 
used  in  the  "  contracts  clause,"  did  the  f ramers  refer  to  the 
obligation  as  fixed  by  positive  law,  that  is,  by  the  law  of  the 
States,  or  to  the  moral  obligation,  or  to  the  obligation  as 
fixed  by  the  law  of  nature,  then  generally  assumed  to  exist, 
or  to  the  obligation  as  determined  by  the  established  prin- 
ciples of  the  common  law,  or  to  the  obligation  as  determined 
by  the  federal  courts  in  the  application  by  them  of  what 
might  be  called  a  federal  common  law  ? 

The  chief  difficulty  which  arises  with  reference  to  the 
positive  law  theory  of  obligation  is  to  determine  how  a  state 
can  obligate  itself  by  a  contract  when  its  own  law  is  con- 
ceived of  as  the  sole  creator  and  definer  of  obligation.  It 
will,  therefore,  be  necessary  to  consider  with  some  care  this 
point. 


CHAPTER  III 
CAN  A  STATE  BE  OBLIGATED  BY  A  CONTRACT? 

In  considering  this,  the  second  question  raised  in  Fletcher 
v.  Peck,  we  are  confronted  by  the  question,  as  already  sug- 
gested, by  what  law  is  a  state  obligated  by  its  contract? 
Austin  laid  it  down  that  a  sovereign  state  could  not  possess 
legal  rights,  must  less  owe  legal  duties.1  Might  there  not 
be  some  other  law  for  determining  the  obligation  of  a  con- 
tract to  which  the  framers  of  the  Constitution  had  refer- 
ence? Particularly  as  to  the  contracts  of  the  States,  is 
there  not  some  superior  law  which  binds  the  States  to  their 
obligations  ?  The  answer  is  at  once  suggested  that  the  Con- 
stitution of  the  United  States  is  the  superior  law  which 
creates  the  obligation.  This  idea  is  clearly  expressed  by 
Taylor,  one  of  the  earlier  writers  in  this  country,  upon  the 
law  of  private  corporations.  He  says :  "  Further,  to  say 
that  the  state,  from  which  emanate  most  of  the  rules  of  law 
composing  the  constitution  [of  a  corporation]  is  a  party  to 
the  agreement  which  the  constitution  embodies,  means  that 
the  state  has  done  an  act  whereby  it  has  expressed  its  inten- 
tion to  bring  itself  within  the  operation  of  some  law  supe- 
rior to  itself,  which  thereupon  manifests  itself  in  legal  rela- 
tions between  the  state  and  the  corporation,  legal  relations 
which  the  state  cannot  alter  at  its  will,  since  they  are  the 
manifestations  of  a  law  superior  to  itself.  That  paramount 
law  is  expressed  in  the  constitution  of  the  United  States."2 
We  do  not  think,  however,  that  this  is  the  correct  view  of 
the  matter,  and  for  proof  thereof  would  refer  to  the  leading 
case  of  Ogden  v.  Saunders.8 

1  Lectures  on  Jurisprudence,  3d  ed.,  pp.  288-292. 

2  Taylor  on  Private  Corporations,  sec.  448. 

3  12  Wheat.  213. 

40 


585]        CAN  A  STATE  BE  OBLIGATED  BY  A  CONTRACT?  4! 

The  question  which  arose  for  determination  in  that  case 
was  whether  a  state  insolvency  law  should  be  declared  in- 
valid as  impairing  the  obligation  of  contracts  in  so  far  as  it 
attempted  to  discharge  debtors  from  liability  upon  their 
contracts,  in  the  case  where  such  contracts  were  made  sub- 
sequently to  the  passage  of  the  law.  Several  views  were 
taken  of  this  question,  which  we  shall  endeavor  to  state  in  a 
very  brief  way.  The  majority  of  the  court  held  that  the 
obligation  of  a  contract  is  determined  by  positive  law,  and 
hence  that  no  obligation  can  arise  out  of  any  contract  which 
will  conflict  with  that  law  as  it  exists  at  the  time  the  con- 
tract is  entered  into. 

The  counsel  for  the  defendant  contended  that  the  Con- 
stitution was  the  supreme  law  of  the  land  and  that,  since  it 
entered  into  the  obligation  of  a  contract  as  much  as  the 
state  insolvency  law  itself  did,  and  since  it  forbade  the  im- 
pairment of  the  obligation  of  contracts;  it  clearly  nullified 
the  operation  of  the  state  insolvency  law.  To  this  obviously 
unsound  argument  Justice  Trimble  gave  the  following  ad- 
mirable answer:4 

The  law  of  the  state,  although  it  constitutes  the  obligation  pf  the 
contract,  is  no  part  of  the  contract  itself ;  nor  is  the  constitution 
either  a  part  of  the  contract,  or  the  supreme  law  of  the  state  in  the 
sense  in  which  the  argument  supposes.  The  constitution  is  the  su- 
preme law  of  the  land  upon  all  subjects  upon  which  it  speaks.  It 
is  the  sovereign  will  of  the  whole  people.  Whatever  this  sovereign 
will  enjoins,  or  forbids,  must  necessarily  be  supreme,  and  must  coun- 
teract the  subordinate  legislative  will  of  the  United  States  and  of 
the  States.  But  on  subjects,  in  relation  to  which  the  sovereign  will 
is  not  declared,  or  fairly  and  necessarily  implied,  the  constitution 
cannot,  with  any  semblance  of  truth,  be  said  to  be  the  supreme  law. 
It  could  not,  with  any  semblance  of  truth,  be  said  that  the  consti- 
tution of  the  United  States  is  the  supreme  law  of  any  state  in  rela- 
tion to  the  solemnities  requisite  for  conveying  real  estate,  or  the 
responsibilities  or  obligations  consequent  upon  the  use  of  certain 
words  in  such  conveyances.  The  constitution  contains  no  law,  no 
declaration  of  the  sovereign  will,  upon  these  subjects,  and  cannot, 
in  the  nature  of  things,  in  relation  to  them,  be  the  supreme  law. 
Even  if  it  were  true,  then,  that  the  law  of  a  state  in  which  a  con- 
tract is  made,  is  part  of  the  contract,  it  would  not  be  true  that  the 
constitution  would  be  part  of  the  contract.  The  constitution  no- 
where professes  to  give  the  law  of  contracts,  or  to  declare  what 
shall  or  shall  not  be  the  obligation  of  contracts.  It  evidently  pre- 

*  12  Wheat.  213  at  325-326. 


42  OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS 

supposes  the  existence  of  contracts  by  the  act  of  the  parties,  and 
the  existence  of  their  obligation,  not  by  authority  of  the  constitu- 
tion, but  by  authority  of  law ;  and  the  preexistence  of  both  the  con- 
tracts and  their  obligation  being  thus  supposed,  the  sovereign  will  is 
announced  that  no  state  shall  pass  any  law  impairing  the  obligation 
of  contracts.  If  it  be  once  ascertained  that  a  contract  existed,  and 
that  an  obligation,  general  or  qualified,  of  whatsoever  kind  had  once 
attached  or  belonged  to  the  contract  by  law,  then,  and  not  till  then 
does  the  supreme  law » speak,  by  declaring  that  obligation  shall  not 
be  impaired. 

This  argument  seems  to  us  conclusive  that  the  effect  of 
the  "  contracts  clause "  is  not  to  make  the  "  obligation  of 
contracts"  a  creation  of  federal  law.  And  although  the 
case  at  hand  involved  only  a  private  contract,  the  argument 
applies  with  equal  force  to  State  contracts,  because  it  is 
based  upon  a  construction  of  the  very  words  of  the  "  con- 
tracts clause"  itself. 

Nor  did  Chief  Justice  Marshall,  who  delivered  the  dis- 
senting opinion,  speaking  for  himself  and  on  behalf  of  Jus- 
tices Story  and  Duval,  use  any  such  argument  as  the  one  we 
have  just  been  considering.  His  argument  is  founded  on 
the  theory  that  the  obligation  of  a  contract  does  not  rest 
upon  positive  law,  but  upon  natural  law,  and  is  therefore 
intrinsic  in  the  contract  itself,  rather  than  imposed  from 
without.  The  theory  of  natural  law  is  elegantly  set  forth. 
And  the  argument  is  a  strong  one,  not  because  of  the  in- 
trinsic soundness  of  the  natural  law  theory,  but  from 
the  consideration  which  Marshall  stated  in  the  following 
manner : 

When  we  advert  to  the  course  of  reading  generally  pursued  by 
American  statesmen  in  early  life,  we  must  suppose,  that  the  framers 
of  our  constitution  were  intimately  acquainted  with  the  writings  of 
those  wise  and  learned  men,  whose  treatises  on  the  laws  of  nature 
and  nations  have  guided  public  opinion  on  the  subjects  of  obliga- 
tion and  contract.  If  we  turn  to  those  treatises,  we  find  them  to 
concur  in  the  declaration,  that  contracts  possess  an  original  intrinsic 
obligation,  derived  from  the  acts  of  free  agents,  and  not  given  by 
government.  We  must  suppose  that  the  framers  of  our  constitu- 
tion, took  the  same  view  of  the  subject,  and  the  language  they  have 
used  confirms  this  opinion. 

Finally,  the  Chief  Justice  pointed  out  that  if  the  view  of 
the  majority  was  correct,  the  States  might  pass  acts  declar- 


587]        CAN  A  STATE  BE  OBLIGATED  BY  A  CONTRACT?  43 

ing  that  all  contracts  should  be  subject  to  legislative  control, 
and  should  be  discharged  as  the  legislature  might  prescribe, 
which  would  thereupon  be  a  condition  upon  which  every 
contract  would  thereafter  be  made ;  "  thus,  one  of  the  most 
important  features  in  the  constitution  of  the  United  States, 
one  which  the  state  of  the  times  most  urgently  required, 
one  on  which  the  good  and  wise  reposed  confidently  for 
securing  the  prosperity  and  harmony  of  our  citizens,  would 
be  prostrate,  and  be  construed  into  an  inanimate,  inopera- 
tive unmeaning  clause."  He  also  made  this  pertinent  sug- 
gestion :  "  Had  the  intention  been  to  confine  the  restriction 
to  laws  which  were  retrospective  in  their  operation,  lan- 
guage could  have  been  found  and  would  have  been  used  to 
convey  this  idea." 

The  argument  thus  made  is,  in  itself,  a  telling  one.  The 
"  Fathers  "  were  versed  in  the  law  of  nature  and  of  nations 
and  did  hold  to  its  principles.  Remembering  that  fact,  and 
viewing  the  language  of  the  "  contracts  clause  "  literally,  one 
is  disposed  to  come  to  the  same  conclusion  that  the  Chief 
Justice  did.5  "This  argument,"  said  Justice  Trimble,  re- 
ferring to  that  of  the  Chief  Justice,  "struck  me,  at  first, 
with  great  force."  Three  of  the  four  majority  justices,  in- 
deed, distinctly  recognized  that  there  was  a  natural  law 
which  sanctioned  the  obligation  of  contracts. 

The  difficulty  with  Marshall's  argument  was  that  it  could 
not  be  applied  to  the  existing  state  of  things.  The  reductio 
ad  absurdum  which  follows  from  endeavoring  to  apply  it 
is  the  best  kind  of  proof,  not  that  the  "Fathers"  did  not 
believe  in  natural  law,  nor  that  they  did  not  intend  to  refer 
to  the  "natural"  obligation  of  contracts,  but  that  the  nat- 
ural law  theory  is  fallacious  and  will  not  work.  Thus,  it 
was  asked,  how,  if  the  "  natural "  obligation  of  all  contracts 
was  guaranteed  by  the  Constitution,  could  a  State  pass  stat- 

5  We  shall,  hereafter,  review  the  evidence  which  can  be  adduced 
to  show  what  the  intention  of  the  framers  was  in  regard  to  the 
"  contracts  clause,"  and  also  to  show  how  much  of  this  evidence 
Marshall  could  have  had  to  guide  him  in  reaching  the  decisions  we 
are  reviewing. 


44  OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS  [588 

utes  of  limitations,  statutes  of  frauds,  statutes  forbidding 
usury  contracts,  gambling  contracts,  contracts  by  persons 
under  twenty-one  years  of  age?  Marshall  answered  that 
statutes  of  frauds,  registration  acts,  etc.,  did  not  impair  the 
obligation,  rather  they  simply  prescribed  forms  and  rules 
of  evidence,  and  that  statutes  of  limitations  act  upon  the 
remedy,  not  upon  the  obligation.  Both  of  these  points  seem 
well  taken,  but  when  he  argues  in  favor  of  the  validity  of 
usury  laws:  "They  declare  the  contract  to  be  void  in  the 
beginning.  They  deny  that  the  instrument  ever  became  a 
contract.  They  deny  it  all  original  obligation  and  cannot 
impair  that  which  never  came  into  existence,"  when  he 
allows  to  the  state  the  right  "to  regulate  contracts,  to  pre- 
scribe the  rules  by  which  they  shall  be  evidenced,  to  pro- 
hibit such  as  may  be  deemed  mischievous,"*  it  seems  that 
the  majority  had  good  reason  for  saying  that  he  thereby 
surrendered  his  whole  argument.  If  a  State  can  forbid  any 
contract  it  deems  mischievous,  it  takes  a  good  deal  of 
searching  to  discover  the  remains  of  any  obligation,  in  the 
natural  law  sense,  still  protected  by  the  federal  Constitu- 
tion. If  it  can  forbid  entirely  the  making  of  contracts,  it 
can  surely  attach  to  them  the  condition  that  they  shall  be 
subject  to  be  discharged  upon  the  insolvency  of  the  debtor 
being  established  after  proceedings  taken. 

The  position  of  the  majority  clearly  is,  therefore,  that 
the  civil  obligation  of  contracts,  at  least  when  it  is  clearly 
and  positively  declared,  is  the  paramount  obligation,  and  is 
the  one  that  the  Constitution  protects. 

But  they  do  not  deny  the  existence  of  a  natural  obligation 
and  its  operation  in  certain  cases.  It  may  be  that  the  "  obli- 
gation "  of  a  "  contract "  between  a  State  of  the  Union  and 
one  of  its  citizens  is  founded  on  natural  rather  than  munici- 
pal law.  At  any  rate,  it  is  desirable  to  understand  more 
clearly  the  views  of  the  majority  in  so  far  as  they  bear  upon 
this  question.  Justice  Washington,  speaking  of  the  uni- 
versal law  of  civilized  nations,  says : 

8  Italics  ours. 


589]        CAN  A  STATE  BE  OBLIGATED  BY  A  CONTRACT?  45 

I,  therefore,  feel  no  objection  to  answer  the  question  asked  by  the 
same  counsel — what  law  is  it  which  constitutes  the  obligation  of  the 
compact  between  Virginia  and  Kentucky?  by  admitting,  that  it  is 
the  common  law  of  nations  which  requires  them  to  perform  it.  I 
admit  further,  that  it  is  this  law  which  creates  the  obligation  of  a 
contract  made  upon  a  desert  spot,  where  no  municipal  law  exists  and 
(which  was  another  case  put  by  the  same  counsel)  which  contract, 
by  the  tacit  assent  of  all  nations,  their  tribunals  are  authorized  to 
enforce.  .  .  .  Whilst  I  admit,  then,  that  this  common  law  of  all 
nations,  which  has  been  mentioned,  may  form  in  part  the  obligation 
of  a  contract,  I  must  unhesitatingly  insist,  that  this  law  is  to  be 
taken  in  strict  subordination  to  the  municipal  laws  of  the  land  where 
the  contract  is  made  or  is  to  be  executed.7 

Justice  Johnson's  ideas  are  found  expressed  in  the  fol- 
lowing quotation : 

Right  and  obligation  are  considered  by  all  ethical  writers  as  cor- 
relative terms.  .  .  .  The  obligation  of  every  contract  will  then  con- 
sist of  that  right  or  power  over  my  will  or  actions,  which  I,  by  my 
contract,  confer  on  another.  And  that  right  and  power  will  be 
found  to  be  measured  neither  by  moral  law  alone,  nor  universal  law 
alone,  nor  by  the  laws  of  society  alone,  but  by  a  combination  of  the 
three, — an  operation  in  which  the  moral  law  is  explained  and  applied 
by  the  law  of  nature,  and  both  modified  and  adapted  to  the  exigen- 
cies of  society  by  positive  law.  The  constitution  was  framed  for 
society  and  an  advanced  state  of  society  ...  in  which  I  will  under- 
take to  say  that  all  the  contracts  of  men  receive  a  relative,  and  not 
a  positive  interpretation:  for  the  rights  of  all  must  be  enjoyed  in 
subserviency  to  the  good  of  the  whole.  The  state  construes  them, 
the  state  applies  them,  and  the  state  decides  how  far  the  social  exer- 
cise of  the  rights  they  give  us  over  each  other  can  be  justly  asserted.8 

Justice  Thompson  did  not  discuss  the  question  whether, 
in  regard  to  State  contracts,  there  was  an  obligation  arising 
from  natural  law.  He  was  contented  with  viewing  the  obli- 
gation as  the  creature  of  municipal  law,  and  confined  him- 
self to  the  contract  at  hand.  Justice  Trimble's  conception 
was  as  follows: 

I  admit,  that  men  have,  by  the  laws  of  nature,  the  right  of  acquir- 
ing, and  possessing  property,  and  the  right  of  contracting  engage- 
ments. I  admit  that  these  natural  rights  have  their  correspondent 
natural  obligations.  I  admit,  that,  in  a  state  of  nature,  when  men 
have  not  submitted  themselves  to  the  controlling  authority  of  civil 
government,  the  natural  obligation  of  contracts  is  co-extensive  with 
the  duty  of  performance.  This  natural  obligation  is  founded  solely 
in  the  principles  of  natural  or  universal  law.  .  .  .  This  natural  obli- 
gation exists  among  sovereign  and  independent  states  and  nations, 
and  amongst  men,  in  a  state  of  nature,  who  have  no  common  supe- 


T  12  Wheat.  213  it  258-259. 
8  12  Wheat.  213  at  281-262. 


46  OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS  [590 

rior,  and  over  whom  none  claim,  or  can  exercise,  controlling  legis- 
lative authority.  But  when  men  form  a  social  compact,  and  organ- 
ize a  civil  government,  they  necessarily  surrender  the  regulation 
and  control  of  these  natural  rights  and  obligations  into  the  hands  of 
the  government.  I  think  it  incontestably  true  that  the  natural  obli- 
gation of  private  contracts  between  individuals  in  society,  ceases, 
and  is  converted  into  a  civil  obligation,  by  the  very  act  of  surren- 
dering the  right  and  power  of  enforcing  performance  into  the  hands 
of  the  government. 

As,  in  a  state  of  nature,  the  natural  obligation  of  a  contract  con- 
sists in  the  right  and  potential  capacity  of  the  individual  to  take  or 
enforce  the  delivery  of  the  thing  due  to  him  by  the  contract,  or  its 
equivalent;  so,  in  the  social  state,  the  obligation  of  a  contract  con- 
sists in  the  efficacy  of  the  civil  law,  which  attaches  to  the  contract, 
and  enforces  its  performance,  or  gives  an  equivalent  in  lieu  of  per- 
formance. From  these  principles  it  seems  to  result  as  a  necessary 
corollary,  that  the  obligation  of  a  contract  made  within  a  sovereign 
state,  must  be  precisely  that  allowed  by  the  law  of  the  State  and 
none  other.  I  say,  allowed,  because  if  there  be  nothing  in  the  mu- 
nicipal law  to  the  contrary,  the  civil  obligation  being,  by  the  very 
nature  of  government,  substituted  for,  and  put  in  the  place  of,  nat- 
ural obligation,  would  be  coextensive  with  it;  but  if  by  positive 
enactions,  the  civil  obligation  is  regulated  and  modified  so  as  that  it 
does  not  correspond  with  the  natural  obligation,  it  is  plain,  the 
extent  of  the  obligation  must  depend  wholly  upon  the  municipal  law.9 

Story,  in  his  Commentaries,  expresses  his  understanding 
of  the  obligatory  nature  of  state  contracts  in  the  following 
manner : 

Nor  is  this  obligatory  force  so  much  the  result  of  the  positive 
declaration  of  the  municipal  as  of  the  general  principles  of  natural 
or  (as  it  is  sometimes  called)  universal  law.  .  .  .  Nay  there  may 
exist  (abstractly  speaking)  a  perfect  obligation  in  contracts  where 
there  is  no  known  and  adequate  means  to  enforce  them.  As,  for 
instance,  between  independent  governments.  ...  So  in  the  same 
government,  where  a  contract  is  made  by  a  State  with  one  of  its 
own  citizens,  which  yet  its  laws  do  not  permit  to  be  enforced  by  any 
action  or  suit.  In  this  predicament  are  the  United  States  who  are 
not  suable  on  any  contracts  made  by  themselves ;  but  no  one  doubts 
that  these  are  still  obligatory  on  the  United  States.  Yet  their  obli- 
gation is  not  recognized  by  any  positive  municipal  law,  in  a  great 
variety  of  cases.  It  depends  altogether  upon  principles  of  public  or 
universal  law.  .  .  .  The  civil  obligation  of  a  contract,  then,  though 
it  can  never  exist  contrary  to  positive  law,  may  arise  or  exist  inde- 
pendently of  it,  and  it  may  exist  notwithstanding  there  may  be  no 
present  adequate  remedy  to  enforce  it.10 

These  quotations  show  how  strong  was  the  influence  of 
the  natural  law  theory  during  the  period  when  the  meaning 
of  the  "contracts  clause"  was  being  outlined.  It  will  be 

9  12  Wheat.  213  at  319-320. 

10  Story  on  the  Constitution,  sec.  1381,  p.  251. 


59 1 ]        CAN  A  STATE  BE  OBLIGATED  BY  A  CONTRACT?  47 

well  to  remember,  in  reading  Fletcher  v.  Peck,  and  Dart- 
mouth College  v.  Woodward,  that  Marshall  felt  that  the 
obligation  of  a  contract  was  not  dependent  on  any  narrow 
and  technical  considerations,  but  on  the  broad  basis  of  nat- 
ural right  and  justice.  And  even  when  the  rest  of  the  court 
disagreed  with  him  and,  being  forced  by  the  circumstances 
of  the  case  to  choose  between  positive  and  natural  law,  he 
stood  out  for  the  supremacy  of  positive  law,  they  did  not 
deny  the  existence  of  a  law  of  nature.  It  is  difficult  to 
state  exactly  what  position  the  majority  of  the  court  took 
in  Ogden  v.  Saunders  in  regard  to  the  obligation  of  con- 
tracts made  between  a  State  and  one  of  its  citizens.  The 
question  was  not  immediately  before  them.  All  the  justices 
admitted  the  existence  and  validity  of  natural  law.  As  to 
private  contracts,  civil  law  supersedes  natural  law,  but  it 
impliedly  adopts  the  principles  of  natural  law  unless  it  ex- 
pressly enacts  otherwise.  It  is  fair  to  -assume  that  they 
either  regarded  a  state  as  bound  by  its  contracts  with  its 
citizens  by  the  sanction  of  natural  law  alone,  or  that  the 
municipal  law  has  impliedly  adopted  the  principles  of  nat- 
ural law  in  this  matter. 

Defenders  of  natural  law  obviously  would  not  find  the 
trouble  that  the  Austinians  have  found  in  holding  that  a 
sovereign  state  may  be  obligated  by  its  contract.  For  this 
the  authority  of  James  Wilson,  the  reputed  author  of  the 
"contracts  clause,"  may  be  cited.  Thus  he  says,  speaking 
of  the  state: 

It  is  an  artificial  person.  It  has  its  affairs  and  its  interests;  it 
has  its  rules ;  it  has  its  obligations ;  and  it  has  its  rights.  If  may 
acquire  property,  distinct  from  that  of  its  members;  it  may  incur 
debts,  to  be  discharged  out  of  the  public  stock,  not  out  of  the  pri- 
vate fortunes  of  individuals:  it  may  be  bound  by  contracts  and  for 
damages  arising  quasi  ex  contractu.11 

So  also  Puf endorf  says :  "  That  no  Prince  hath  power  to 
release  himself  from  his  oath,  when  there  lies  no  objection 
either  against  the  validity  of  his  taking  it,  or  the  matter  con- 
tained in  it,  or  the  circumstances  belonging  to  it,  upon  pre- 

11  Wilson's  Works,  ed.  Andrews,  p.  272. 


48  OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS  [592 

tence  that  it  is  lawful  for  him  to  relieve  his  subjects  in  some 
particular  oaths,  I  think  is  evident.  For  the  oaths  which  he 
has  power  to  vacate  in  his  subjects  have  always  this  condi- 
tion annexed  to  them  if  it  please  the  sovereign.  And  'tis 
certain  it  would  be  impossible  to  bind  any  obligation  upon 
a  man  if  he  reserves  to  himself  a  power  to  break  from  it 
whenever  he  thinks  fit/'  Further  he  says :  "  and  therefore 
upon  the  whole  all  contracts  made  by  the  prince  oblige  the 
commonwealth,  unless  they  are  manifestly  absurd  or  unjust. 
And  when  the  case  is  doubtful  'tis  always  to  be  presumed 
in  favor  of  the  prince.  .  .  .  And  so  whatever  a  free  people 
contract,  devolves  upon  and  obliges  the  person  they  after- 
wards confer  sovereignty  upon,  though  they  give  him  never 
so  full  and  absolute  a  power."12 

We  have  seen,  therefore,  that  it  was  the  natural  law 
theory  of  the  obligation  of  a  contract  that  was  looked  to  as 
furnishing  the  test  of  the  obligation  of  state  contracts,  and 
that,  upon  this  theory,  an  obligation  exists  entirely  irre- 
spective of  the  legal  omnipotence — the  sovereignty — of  one 
of  the  contracting  parties.  The  English  Parliament  could 
be  as  completely  obligated  by  its  contract  as  any  of  our  state 
legislatures  by  theirs.  It  is  therefore  clear  that  the  criticism 
so  often  made  of  the  Dartmouth  College  case,  that  the  Eng- 
lish Parliament  could  not  have  been  obligated  by  any  con- 
tract in  connection  with  the  grant  of  the  college  charter,  is 
entirely  beside  the  point.  The  argument  is  a  valid  one, 
when  it  is  used  to  show  that  no  contract  could  have  been 
intended,  under  the  well  understood  principles  of  law  exist- 
ing when  the  charter  was  granted ;  but  if  it  is  attempted  to 
go  farther,  and  to  say  that  there  could  not  possibly  have 
been  any  contract,  because  of  the  legal  omnipotence  of  Par- 
liament, we  think  the  argument  overlooks  the  meaning  which 
the  court  has  attributed  to  the  word  "  obligation."  And  we 
would  further  point  out  that,  except  in  so  far  as  the  legisla- 
tures of  the  states  are  restrained  by  constitutional  provi- 
sions of  their  own,  they  are  as  legally  omnipotent  as  Pariia- 

12  Law  of  Nature  and  Nations,  Book  8,  chap,  x,  sec.  3,  pp.  865-866. 


593]         CAN  A  STATE  BE  OBLIGATED  BY  A  CONTRACT?  49 

ment,  and  if  Parliament  cannot  obligate  itself,  they  are 
equally  as  incapable  of  binding  themselves  by  contract. 

If  the  federal  courts  do,  as  a  matter  of  practice,  construe 
state  contracts  by  applying  principles  of  natural  right  and 
justice,  it  becomes  a  matter  of  no  practical  importance 
whether  we  allow  these  principles  an  independent  author- 
ity or  regard  them  as  impliedly  adopted  by  the  municipal 
law  of  the  States.  The  only  difference  which  one  would 
imagine  might  result  would  be  an  increased  respect  for  the 
decisions  of  the  state  courts,  if  the  question  to  be  decided 
is  avowedly  one  of  state  law.  The  attitude  of  the  federal 
courts  towards  state  decisions,  in  this  class  of  cases,  is  in- 
deed one  of  great  independence,  but  this  does  not  neces- 
sarily lead  to  the  conclusion  that  the  federal  courts  do  not 
rest  the  obligation  of  contracts  upon  state  law.  In  the  first 
place  this  independence  of  judgment  is  asserted  even  where 
the  determination  of  the  obligation  of  a  contract  necessi- 
tates a  construction  of  the  state  constitution  or  statutes.18 
In  the  second  place,  in  cases  where  the  federal  jurisdiction 
is  based  upon  diversity  of  citizenship,  and  where  it  is  gener- 
ally admitted,  therefore,  that  the  federal  courts  are  apply- 
ing state  law,  these  courts  may  exercise  an  independent 
judgment  as  to  what  the  state  law  is ;  and  in  matters  of  com- 
mercial law  and  general  jurisprudence  they  consider  them- 
selves peculiarly  free  from  any  obligation  to  follow  state 
decisions.14 

An  interesting  case  that  comes  rather  close  to  settling  the 
theoretical  question  we  are  discussing  and  which  yet  does 
not  quite  do  so,  is  Douglas  v.  Kentucky,15  where  the  court 
refused  to  apply  the  rule  it  had  previously  established  that 
"  if  the  contract,  when  made,  was  valid  by  the  laws  of  the 
State  as  then  expounded  by  all  departments  of  the  govern- 
ment, and  administered  in  its  courts  of  justice,  its  validity 
and  obligation  cannot  be  impaired  by  any  subsequent  action 

"Jefferson  Branch  Bank  v.  Skelly,  I  Black,  426. 

14  Burgess  v.  Seligman,  107  U.  S.  20;  Swift  v.  Tyson,  16  Pet  I. 

«  168  U.  S.  488. 

4 


5O  OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS  [$94 

of  legislation,  or  decision  of  its  courts  altering  the  construc- 
tion of  the  law.1® 

Here  the  facts  were  that  the  legislature  had  granted  a 
lottery  privilege  to  a  municipality,  which  had  sold  it  to  a 
private  individual.  Before  the  latter  resold  it,  there  had 
been  a  decision  of  the  highest  court  of  the  State  holding 
that  a  grantee  or  his  assigns  who  invested  money  on  the 
faith  of  a  lottery  grant,  acquired  a  legal  right  thereto,  and, 
in  addition,  a  quo  warranto  had  been  issued  against  the  pur- 
chaser of  the  lottery  in  dispute  and  had  been  decided  in 
favor  of  the  owner.  On  the  strength  of  these  decisions  the 
plaintiff  purchased  the  lottery.  Later  a  repealing  act  was 
passed.  The  Court  of  Appeals  of  Kentucky  reversed  itself 
and  allowed  the  repealing  act  to  stand,  and  an  appeal  was 
taken  to  the  United  States  Supreme  Court.  Thus,  the  case 
contained  facts  which  brought  it  completely  within  the  rule 
laid  down  by  Taney  in  Life  Insurance  Co.  v.  Debolt,  and 
adopted  by  the  whole  court  in  Gelpcke  v.  Dubuque.  There 
was  the  prior  state  decision  holding  that  a  lottery  franchise 
was  a  valid  contract;  there  was  a  purchase  made  on  the 
faith  of  that  decision,  whereby  the  purchaser  and  the  state, 
on  the  doctrine  of  novation,  entered  into  a  new  contract ; 
there  was  a  subsequent  reversal  of  the  former  decision  by 
the  state  court,  and  an  application  by  the  state  court  of  a 
statute  repealing  the  grant.  Had  the  question  been  consid- 
ered to  be  only  whether  or  not,  at  the  time  the  plaintiff  pur- 
chased the  lottery,  the  state  law  regarded  him  as  obtaining 
a  legal  title  thereto  good  as  against  the  State,  as  acquiring 
a  legal  right  that  the  lottery  grant  should  not  be  repealed, 
it  should  have  been  answered  in  the  affirmative,  certainly  if 
the  rule  of  Gelpcke  v.  Dubuque  was  to  be  applied.  But  the 
court  refused  to  apply  the  rule  of  Gelpcke  v.  Dubuque. 
The  court  said :  "  The  defendant  insists  that  his  rights  having 
been  acquired  when  these  decisions  of  the  highest  court  of 
Kentucky  were  in  full  force,  should  be  protected  according 


16  Life  Insurance  &  T.  Co.  v.  Debolt,  16  How.  416;  Gelpcke  v. 
Dubuque,  i  Wall.  175. 


595]         CAN  A  STATE  BE  OBLIGATED  BY  A  CONTRACT?  5! 

to  the  law  of  the  state  as  it  was  adjudged  to  be  when  those 
rights  attached.  But  is  this  court  required  to  accept  the 
principles  announced  by  the  state  court  as  to  the  extent  to 
which  the  contract  clause  of  the  Federal  Constitution  re- 
stricts the  powers  of  the  state  Legislature?  Clearly  not. 
.  .  .  This  court  must  determine — indeed  it  cannot  consis- 
tently with  its  duty  refuse  to  determine — upon  its  own  re- 
sponsibility, in  each  case  as  it  arises,  whether  that  which  a 
party  seeks  to  have  protected  under  the  contract  clause  of 
the  Constitution  of  the  United  States  is  a  contract  the  obli- 
gation of  which  is  protected  by  that  instrument  against  hos- 
tile state  legislation." 

The  rule  of  Gelpcke  v.  Dubuque  and  Life  Insurance  Co. 
v.  Debolt  is  rather  clearly  based  on  the  idea  that  the  validity 
and  obligation  of  the  contract  is  determined  by  state  law, 
and  for  this  reason  the  decisions  in  force  at  the  time  of  the 
formation  of  the  contract  are  to  be  regarded  as  fixing  its 
obligation.  It  is  difficult  to  say,  however,  whether  Justice 
Harlan  refused  to  regard  those  decisions,  on  the  ground 
that  the  federal  court  was  not  administering  state  law  at  all, 
or  simply  upon  the  ground  that  the  rule  of  Gelpcke  v.  Du- 
buque was  a  rule  of  policy,  which  did  not  obviate  the  duty, 
incumbent  upon  the  court  of  exercising  an  independent 
judgment  and,  when  the  occasion  required,  of  making  an 
exception  to  the  rule. 

As  to  what  contracts  the  States  may  make  and  what  they 
may  not  make,  the  Supreme  Court  has  made  a  number  of 
somewhat  varied  rulings.  From  the  nature  of  the  case,  it 
is  difficult  to  draw  a  line  between  contracts  which  the  States 
may  make  and  those  which  they  may  not  make.  In  the 
Ohio  Bank  Tax  cases17  in  which  the  question  of  the  validity 
of  contracts  as  to  exemption  from  taxation  was  reargued, 
the  majority  simply  argued  that  the  power  of  a  state  to  con- 
tract was  a  result  of  its  sovereignty,  and  that  to  deny  it  this 
power  was  to  deny  it  its  sovereignty.  The  court  has,  how- 

17  Piqua  Branch  Bank  v.  Knoop,  16  How.  369,  and  Ohio  Life  In- 
surance Co.  v.  Debolt,  1 6  How.  416. 


52  OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS  [$96 

ever,  held  that  the  States  cannot  contract  away  their 
power18  of  eminent  domain,  or  their  police  power,19  nor  any 
of  their  power  to  supervise  and  regulate  the  forms  of  ad- 
ministering justice.20  A  State  cannot  contract  concerning 
governmental  subjects,  hence  it  cannot  contract  with  the 
citizens  of  a  town  that,  upon  fulfilling  certain  conditions,  it 
will  establish  the  county-seat  at  that  place.21  Land  under 
navigable  waters  cannot  be  alienated  except  in  parcels  which 
can  be  disposed  of  without  detriment  to  the  public  interest 
in  the  lands  and  waters  remaining.22  On  the  other  hand, 
perpetual  corporate,  ferry,  turnpike,  gas,  water,  railroad 
and  street  railway  franchises  have  been  held  to  be  contracts 
within  the  protection  of  the  "contracts  clause."  These 
privileges  may  be  made  exclusive  as  well.  Finally,  the 
State  may  grant  exemptions  from  rate  regulation  at  the 
hands  of  the  legislature.23 

Obviously  the  court  has  not  been  particularly  consistent 
in  its  rulings  as  to  what  may  and  what  may  not  be  the  sub- 
ject of  contracts  by  the  States.  But  upon  principles  of 
natural  law  or  general  jurisprudence  there  is  abundance  of 
room  for  differences  of  opinion  as  to  the  proper  limits  of 
the  power  of  states  to  contract.  That  even  the  writers 
upon  natural  law  placed  some  limits  upon  the  right  of  the 
state  to  contract  may  be  seen  from  a  rather  interesting  pas- 
sage from  Pufendorf.  He  says: 

What  hath  been  said  of  the  contracts  of  princes  may  also  be  said 
of  their  grants  and  donations,  viz:  that  they  cannot  be  recalled  by 
the  successors  where  they  were  made  upon  fair  and  reasonable  rea- 
sons. .  .  .  What  hath  been  said  with  relation  to  grants  may  also 
be  applied  to  privileges  and  immunities,  namely,  that  it  ought  to  be 
considered  upon  what  reasons  and  with  what  moderation  and  cau- 
tion they  were  given,  and  whether  they  were  consistent  with  the 
peace  and  security  of  the  state,  for  without  dispute,  these  things  are 
of  far  greater  concern  than  the  unwary  easiness  of  the  prince.  And 

18  Cincinnati  y.  Louisville  &  N.  R.  Co.,  223  U.  S.  390. 

19  Stone  v.  Mississippi,  101  U.  S.  814. 

20  Bank  of  Columbia  v.  Okely,  4  Wheat.  235,  245;  and  Cairo,  etc. 
R.  Co.  v.  Hecht,  95  U.  S.  168. 

21  Newton  v.  Commissioners,  100  U.  S.  548. 

82  Illinois  Central  R.  Co.  v.  Illinois,  146  U.  S.  387. 

23  See  the  special  chapters  on  franchises  and  rate  exemptions. 


597]        CAN  A  STATE  BE  OBLIGATED  BY  A  CONTRACT?  53 

indeed  all  privileges  are  to  be  confined  under  such  limitations  when- 
ever they  begin  to  lie  heavy  upon  the  other  subjects.24 

It  is  apparent  that  in  determining,  in  a  concrete  case, 
whether  or  not  a  contract  with  the  state  exists,  as,  for  ex- 
ample, in  the  case  of  the  grant  of  corporate  privileges,  the 
theory  and  practice  upon  the  subject  of  state  contracts  must 
be  given  some  consideration,  even  if  the  ultimate  sanction 
of  the  contract  be  natural  or  universal  law.  The  reason  is 
that  natural  law  only  renders  obligatory  that  to  which  the 
parties  intend  to  bind  themselves,  and  in  a  state  whose  mu- 
nicipal law  has  never  recognized  any  contractual  relation 
between  the  state  and  its  grantee  in  the  granting  of  cor- 
porate franchises,  it  would  be  difficult  to  say  that  a  contract 
was  intended  by  the  parties.  Hence,  in  considering  the 
Dartmouth  College  case,  it  will  be  necessary  to  examine  the 
doctrines  of  the  common  law  and  the  established  parlia- 
mentary precedents  in  regard  to  corporate  grants  before  it 
can  fairly  be  determined  whether  an  obligatory  contract, 
even  upon  principles  of  natural  law,  was  created  by  the 
grant. 

Before  beginning  the  discussion  of  that  case,  however,  it 
is  desirable  to  see  what  are  the  essentials  of  an  obligatory 
state  contract  upon  positive  law  principles  alone,  for  modern 
jurists  generally  agree  that  it  is  proper  to  speak  of  a  state 
being  obligated  by  a  contract  merely  under  the  sanction  of 
its  own  municipal  law. 

Recognizing  the  fact  which  we  have  already  stated,  that 
obligation  is  the  legal  relationship  between  the  parties,  that 
it  is,  from  one  point  of  view,  the  legal  duty  owed  by  one 
person  to  another,  and  from  another  point  of  view,  the  legal 
right  or  power  which  that  other  has  to  control  the  actions 
of  the  first,  and  recognizing  that  this  right  and  duty  are  the 
creatures  of  law,  Austin  laid  it  down  that  the  state,  which 
was  the  source  of  all  law,  could  not  be  limited  or  bound  by 
law,  and  therefore  could  owe  no  legal  duties,  could  be  sub- 

2*  Puf endorf ,  p.  867. 


54  OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS  [598 

ject  to  no  legal  obligations.25  In  fact,  he  held  that  it  could 
possess  no  legal  rights.  This  opinion  is  likewise  held  by 
Markby26  and  by  Amos,27  and  it  may  be  found  in  one,  at 
any  rate,  of  the  decisions  of  the  Supreme  Court  of  the 
United  States,  for,  in  Kawanakoa  v.  Polybank,28  Justice 
Holmes,  in  extending  the  doctrine  of  the  non-suability  of 
the  state  to  protect  the  government  of  the  territory  of 
Hawaii,  explained  the  theory  as  follows:  "A  sovereign  is 
exempt  from  suit,  not  because  of  any  formal  conception  or 
absolete  theory,  but  on  the  logical  and  practical  ground  that 
there  can  be  no  legal  right  as  against  the  authority  that 
makes  the  law  on  which  the  right  depends." 

Recent  writers  have  shown  very  clearly,  however,  that 
the  subject  may  have  rights  as  against  the  sovereign,  be- 
cause that  which  makes  any  other  right  a  legal  right  is 
merely  its  recognition  as  such  by  the  sovereign;  if,  there- 
fore, the  sovereign  recognizes  the  existence  of  rights  as 
against  itself,  these  rights  are  legal  rights.  There  is  no 
higher  sanction  to  any  legal  right  than  this.29  So  Brown 
says,  in  his  work,  The  Austinian  Theory  of  Law :  "  Sov- 
ereignty does  not  preclude  the  notion  of  obligation,  but  only 
the  notion  of  limitation  by  a  power  external  to  itself." 
Pollock  says :  "  In  practice,  individual  citizens  may  count  on 
the  submission  of  the  State  to  its  own  tribunals  (whatever 
the  extent  of  it  may  be)  not  being  arbitrarily  revoked.  The 
security  is  the  same,  in  the  last  resort,  that  we  have  for  the 
due  administration  and  enforcement  of  the  ordinary  law 
binding  on  subjects."  Salmond  is  so  excellent  upon  this 
point  that  we  shall  quote  his  argument  in  full.  He  says : 

A  subject  may  claim  rights  against  the  state,  no  less  than  against 
another  subject.  He  can  institute  proceedings  against  the  state  for 
the  determination  and  recognition  of  these  rights  in  due  course  of 

25  Austin,  Jurisprudence,  3d  ed.,  pp.  288-292. 

26  Markby,  sec.  154,  p.  92. 

27  Amos,  Science  of  Jurisprudence,  p.  77. 
.282os  U.  S.  349. 

29  See  Pollock,  First  Book  of  Jurisprudence,  p.  63  ff.;  Brown,  Thj 
Austinian  Theory  of  Law,  p.  194;  Salmond,  p.  202 ff.;  Holland, 
p.  126. 


599]         CAN  A  STATE  BE  OBLIGATED  BY  A  CONTRACT?  5$ 

law,  and  he  can  obtain  judgment  in  his  favor,  recognizing  their  ex- 
istence or  awarding  to  him  compensation  for  their  infringement. 
But  there  can  be  no  enforcement  of  that  judgment.  What  duties 
the  state  recognizes  as  owing  by  it  to  it's  subjects,  it  fulfills  of  its 
own  free  will  and  unconstrained  good  pleasure.  The  strength  of 
the  law  is  none  other  than  the  strength  of  the  state,  and  cannot  be 
turned  or  used  against  the  state  whose  strength  it  is.  The  rights 
of  the  subject  against  the  state  are  therefore  imperfect.  They  ob- 
tain legal  recognition  but  no  legal  enforcement. 

The  fact  that  the  element  of  enforcement  is  thus  absent  in  the 
case  of  rights  against  the  state  has  induced  many  writers  to  deny 
that  these  are  legal  rights  at  all.  But  as  we  have  already  seen,  we 
need  not  so  narrowly  define  the  term  legal  right,  as  to  include  only 
those  claims  that  are  legally  enforced.  It  is  equally  logical  and 
more  convenient  to  include  within  the  term  all  those  claims  that  are 
legally  recognized  in  the  administration  of  justice.  All  rights  against 
the  state  are  not  legal,  any  more  than  all  rights  against  private  per- 
sons are  legal.  But  some  of  them  are;  those,  namely,  which  can  be 
sued  for  in  courts  of  justice,  and  the  existence  and.  limits  of  which 
will  be  judicially  determined  in  accordance  with  fixed  principles  of 
law,  redress  or  compensation  being  awarded  for  any  violation  of 
them.  To  hold  the  contrary  and  to  deny  the  name  of  legal  right 
or  duty  in  all  cases  in  which  the  state  is  the  defendant  is  to  enter 
upon  a  grave  conflict  with  legal  and  popular  speech  and  thought. 
In  the  language  of  lawyers,  as  in  that  of  laymen,  a  contract  with 
the  state  is  as  much  a  source  of  legal  rights  and  obligations  as  is  a 
contract  between  two  private  persons;  and  the  right  of  the  holder 
of  consols  is  as  much  a  legal  right,  as  is  that  of  a  debenture  holder 
in  a  public  company.  It  is  not  to  the  point  to  say  that  rights  against 
the  state  are  held  at  the  state's  good  pleasure,  and  are  therefore  not 
legal  rights  at  all;  for  all  other  legal  rights  are  in  the  same  posi- 
tion. They  are  legal  rights  not  because  the  state  is  bound  to  recog- 
nize them,  but  because  it  does  so. 

Whether  rights  against  the  state  can  properly  be  termed  legal 
depends  simply  on  whether  judicial  proceedings  in  which  the  state 
is  the  defendant  are  properly  included  within  the  administration  of 
justice.  For  if  they  are  rightly  so  included,  the  principles  by  which 
they  are  governed  are  true  principles  of  law,  and  the  right's  defined 
by  these  legal  principles  are  true  legal  rights.  The  boundary  line 
of  the  administration  of  justice  has  been  traced  in  a  previous  chap- 
ter. We  there  saw  sufficient  reason  for  including  not  only  the 
direct  enforcement  of  justice  but  all  other  judicial  functions  exer- 
cised by  courts  of  justice.  This  is  the  ordinary  use  of  the  term  and 
it  seems  open  to  no  logical  objection. 

And  a  further  quotation  from  Brown  will,  perhaps,  aid  in 
understanding  the  matter : 

If  a  sovereign,  having  laid  down  a  law  that  contracts  shall  be 
enforced^  enters  into  contracts  with  its  own  subjects,  and  if  those 
contracts  are  enforced  as  a  matter  of  fact  by  its  courts  even  as 
against  the  sovereign,  then  it  is  impossible  to  deny  that  the  sovereign 
is  under  a  legal  duty  towards  its  subjects.  We  cannot  refuse  to 
describe  the  sovereign's  liability  as  a  legal  duty  on  the  ground  that 
the  sanction  is  self  imposed,  if  as  a  matter  of  fact  the  sanction  is 


56  OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS  [6oO 

invariably  admitted  by  the  sovereign,  and  applied  by  the  courts. 
Austin's  failure  to  recognize  the  fact  is  a  conclusive  illustration  of 
the  need  for  revising  his  theory  of  sovereignty.80 

So,  also,  Holland  says : 

Indeed  it  is  not  improper  to  talk  of  the  state  as  having  duties, 
namely  such  as  it  prescribes  to  itself,  though  it  has  the  physical 
power  to  disregard  and  the  constitutional  power  to  repudiate  them. 
Such  duties  as  we  often  see  enforced,  e.g.  in  England,  principally, 
but  not  exclusively  by  a  Petition  of  Right,  which  is  lodged  with  the 
Home  Secretary,  and,  after  due  investigation,  receives,  in  suitable 
cases,  the  Royal  fiat  "  let  right  be  done."  The  subsequent  proceed- 
ings follow  the  course  of  an  ordinary  action.  This  remedy  is  inap- 
plicable in  cases  of  tort.31 

Although  this,  the  latest  view  of  modern  jurists,  allows 
that  the  state  may  be  under  legal  obligations,  and  goes  far 
toward  supporting  the  doctrine  that  a  legally  omnipotent 
legislature  is  obligated  by  its  grant  of  lands  or  franchises, 
there  is,  nevertheless,  a  certain  difficulty  in  applying  the 
conception  to  the  concrete  case  of  a  grant  by  the  state. 

Although  these  same  jurists  deny  that  a  grant  is,  gener- 
ally speaking,  a  contract,  nevertheless,  we  have  seen  that, 
for  the  purposes  of  the  "contracts  clause"  it  is  to  be  so 
regarded,  and  that  the  only  way  in  which  it  can  be  so  re- 
garded is  by  implying  an  agreement  not  to  revoke  the  grant. 
Now  there  is  no  legal  procedure  in  any  state,  whose  govern- 
ment is  organized  without  constitutional  limitations,  by 
which  any  such  contract  can  be  recognized,  let  alone  en- 
forced. That  is  to  say,  Parliament,  for  example,  has  pro- 
vided for  a  legal  recognition  as  against  itself,  of  the  obli- 
gation which  it  creates  when  it  agrees  to  pay  a  certain  sum 
of  money  at  a  certain  time.  It  has  not  provided  for  any 
direct  legal  recognition  of  the  specific  contract  not  to  repeal 
a  franchise  granted  or  a  land  grant  made.  The  point,  of 
course,  is  a  rather  finely  drawn  one.  We  think  it  correct 
to  say,  however,  that,  in  the  eye  of  the  law,  to-day  as  well 
as  in  Blackstone's  time,  the  legal  title  which  an  individual 
has  to  a  piece  of  land  conveyed  to  him  by  the  state  is  r.s 

80  Brown,  The  Austinian  Theory  of  Law,  p.  194. 

81  Holland,  Jurisprudence,  loth  ed.,  p.  126. 


6OIJ         CAN  A  STATE  BE  OBLIGATED  BY  A  CONTRACT?  57 

strong  as  that  which  he  has  to  a  similar  piece  of  land  con- 
veyed to  him  by  another  individual.  And  we  think  it  prob- 
ably correct  to  say  that,  in  Blackstone's  time,  a  grant  of 
franchises  by  the  Crown  or  by  Parliament  was  regarded  as 
conveying  legal  rights — legal  rights,  the  court  would  have 
said,  had  it  been  possible  to  bring  the  abstract  question  be- 
fore them,  even  as  against  Parliament.  In  this  case,  we 
think  it  correct  to  say  that  state  grants  give  rise,  by  munici- 
pal law,  to  legal  rights  against  the  state :  (and,  if  the  grant 
be  regarded  as  a  contractual  relation,  that  the  right  of  the 
individual  and  the  corresponding  duty  of  the  state  may 
properly  be  spoken  of  as  a  legal  obligation). 

The  principal  question,  then,  in  the  Dartmouth  College 
case,  must  be  whether  or  not  corporate  charters — at  least 
the  charters  of  colleges — were  regarded,  at  the  time  of  the 
grant  in  question,  as  a  species  of  private  property.  This 
inquiry  is  of  almost  equal  importance  whether  the  existence 
of  the  obligation  is  to  be  determined  by  natural  or  municipal 
law.  Finally,  it  may  be  noted  that,  in  a  state  whose  gov- 
ernment is  organized  with  a  legally  omnipotent  Parliament, 
as  is  England,  it  may  well  be  that  the  question  of  the  invio- 
lability of  private  property  or  of  state  grants  can  not  be 
determined  entirely  by  reference  to  the  law  as  administered 
by  the  courts.  Reference  must  also  be  made  to  the  actual 
practice  of  the  sovereign  body  which,  perhaps  as  much  as 
anything  else,  will  show  the  nature  of  the  rights  of  indi- 
viduals. 


CHAPTER  IV 
THE  DARTMOUTH  COLLEGE  CASE 

We  have  reserved  for  consideration  in  this  chapter  the 
most  famous  of  all  the  cases  dealing  with  the  "contracts 
clause  " — Trustees  of  Dartmouth  College  v.  Woodward.1 

The  broad  constitutional  question  involved  in  that  case 
was  whether  a  charter  of  incorporation  constituted  a  con- 
tract within  the  protection  of  the  "  contracts  clause  "  of  the 
United  States  Constitution.  But  this  was  by  no  means  the 
only  question  that  had  to  be  decided.  Those  who  have 
found  fault  with  the  most  important  principle  there  laid 
down  have  also  tried  to  discredit  the  decision  by  pointing 
out  errors  of  law  in  regard  to  other  points  involved,  and 
errors  in  the  statement  of  facts,  each  of  which,  they  contend, 
are  sufficient  to  have  caused  a  reversal  of  the  whole  decision. 
The  case,  therefore,  cannot  be  fairly  discussed,  nor  really 
understood,  without  some  consideration  of  these  collateral 
questions. 

Dartmouth  College  was  incorporated  by  a  charter  from 
the  Crown  (signed  in  behalf  of  the  king  by  Governor  Went- 
worth  of  New  Hampshire)  granted  in  1769.  It  cannot  be 
gainsaid  that,  in  the  year  1816,  and  ever  since  its  incorpora- 
tion, practically,  Dartmouth  College  had  been  a  "  going  con- 
cern/' with  lands,  buildings,  trustees,  faculty  and  students, 
all  located  in  what  was,  after  1776,  the  State  of  New  Hamp- 
shire. In  the  year  1816,  the  legislature  of  New  Hamp- 
shire passed  three  laws  amending  the  charter  of  the  college 
so  as  to  change  its  name  to  "The  Trustees  of  Dartmouth 
University  " ;  to  change  the  number  of  trustees  from  twelve 
to  twenty-one,  of  whom  nine  should  constitute  a  quorum; 
to  provide  that  the  nine  new  trustees  be  appointed  by  the 

1 4  Wheat.  518. 

58 


603]  THE  DARTMOUTH  COLLEGE  CASE  59 

Governor  and  Council ;  to  provide  for  a  board  of  overseers 
of  twenty-five  members,  appointed  by  the  Governor  and 
Council,  with  power  to  veto  the  acts  of  the  trustees  relative 
to  the  appointment  of  the  president  and  faculty  and  to  other 
administrative  matters;  to  provide  that  each  of  the  two 
boards  should  have  power  to  remove  any  of  their  members ; 
and  to  give  the  trustees  power  to  organize  colleges  in  the 
university.  These  remarkable  amendments,  it  will  easily 
be  perceived,  were  drawn  up  to  accomplish  a  particular  pur- 
pose. There  had  been  a  schism  in  the  old  board  of  trustees. 
The  rock  upon  which  the  board  had  split,  by  a  vote  of  eight 
to  four,  was  the  president  of  the  college,  Dr.  John  Whee- 
lock,  son  of  the  founder.  The  history  of  the  events  leading 
up  to  the  passage  of  the  amending  acts  is  interesting.  As 
recited  by  Shirley,  in  the  work  already  referred  to,  it  shows 
the  spread  of  the  controversy  until,  from  a  quarrel  among 
the  Trustees  of  Dartmouth  College,  it  assumed  the  shape 
of  a  state-wide  political  controversy,  the  sides  of  which 
were  taken  by  the  Federalists  and  the  Anti-Federalists  re- 
spectively,2 but  all  this  is  immaterial  to  a  discussion  of  the 
case  from  a  legal  standpoint.3  It  will  suffice  to  point  out 
that  the  addition  of  the  nine  new  trustees  was  evidently  in- 
tended to  turn  the  party  of  the  minority  into  the  party  of 
the  majority.  The  old  trustees  refused  to  accept  the  amend- 
ments and  removed  Woodward,  the  secretary  and  treasurer 
of  the  corporation,  who  joined  the  camp  of  the  enemy, 
taking  with  him  the  seal  and  record  books  of  Dartmouth 
College,  and  was  made  secretary  and  treasurer  of  the  newly 
organized  "  Dartmouth  University."  The  old  trustees  there- 
upon brought  an  action  of  trover  in  the  name  of  the  old 
corporation  to  recover  their  seal  and  records  from  Wood- 

2  According  to  Shirley  in  his  work  entitled  "  The  Dartmouth  Col- 
lege Causes,"  which  is  accepted  by  H.  C.  Lodge  in  his  Life  of  Daniel 
Webster. 

3  It  has  been  contended  that  the  decision  was  chiefly  due  to  the 
political  aspect  of  the  case,  which  Webster  astutely  played  upon  in 
his  argument  before  the  Supreme  Court — Lodge,  Life  of  Webster, 
p.  89 — but  this  inference,  of  course,  cannot  with  fairness  be  drawn 
before  the  legal  questions  have  been  examined. 


6O  OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS  [604 

ward,  and  this  action  it  was  that  was  brought  before  the 
Supreme  Court.  It  was  contended  before  that  court  that 
the  acts  of  1816  impaired  the  obligation  of  the  contract  con- 
tained in  the  charter. 

It  is  important  to  set  out  the  facts  in  slightly  more  detail, 
particularly  the  circumstances  surrounding  the  grant  of  the 
charter,  inasmuch  as  Mr.  Shirley,  in  his  book  entitled  "  The 
Dartmouth  College  Causes,"  already  referred  to,  has  chal- 
lenged the  statement  of  facts  which  Chief  Justice  Marshall 
made  in  delivering  his  opinion  as  erroneous  and  intention- 
ally misleading,  and  as  giving  an  entirely  different  aspect 
to  the  case  from  that  which  it  would  otherwise  have  had. 

The  facts  of  the  case  were  found  by  a  special  verdict  of 
the  jury  (which  really  was  agreed  upon  by  stipulation  be- 
tween counsel),  which  is  set  out  in  full  in  Wheat on's  report. 
It  was  upon  these  facts  that  the  case  came  before  the  Su- 
preme Court.     The  verdict  began  by  setting  forth  the  char- 
ter which,  as  usual,  set  out  in  the  preamble  the  facts  which 
induced  the  Crown  to  make  the  grant.     The  essential  facts 
there  set  out  are:  That  the  Reverend  Eleazer  Wheelock 
had,  many  years  before,  set  on  foot,  at  his  own  expense  and 
on  his  own  estate,  an  Indian  Charity  School.     Others  had 
lent  pecuniary  assistance  and  the  school  had  prospered  to 
such  an  extent  that  it  was  thought  advisable  to  raise  funds 
in  England,  which  was  done,  the  funds  being  placed  in  the 
hands  of  certain  trustees  residing  there.     It  further  recited 
that  Wheelock  represented  that  he  had  authorized  the  Eng- 
lish trustees  to  select  a  fitting  location  for  the  school,  and 
had  set  before  them  the  offers  of  grants  of  land  that  had 
been  made  by  several  of  the  governments  in  America ;  that 
a  large  number  of  proprietors  of  lands  in  western  New 
Hampshire,  considering  that  such  a  location  would  be  ad- 
vantageous for  carrying  out  the  work  among  the  Indians, 
"  and  also,  considering,  that  without  the  least  impediment 
to  the  said  design,  the  same  school  may  be  enlarged  and 
improved  to  promote  learning  among  the  English,  and  be  a 
means  to  supply  a  great  number  of  churches  and  congrega- 


605]  THE  DARTMOUTH  COLLEGE  CASE  6 1 

tions,  which  are  likely  soon  to  be  formed  in  that  new  coun- 
try, with  a  learned  and  orthodox  ministry,  they  the  said 
proprietors  have  promised  large  tracts  of  land,  for  the  uses 
aforesaid,  provided  the  school  shall  be  settled  in  the  western 
part  of  our  said  province  " ;  that  the  English  trustees  chose 
the  same  location;  and  that  "the  said  Wheelock  has  also 
represented  the  necessity  of  a  legal  incorporation,  in  order 
to  the  safety  and  well  being  of  said  seminary,  and  its  being 
capable  of  the  tenure  and  disposal  of  lands  and  bequests 
for  the  use  of  the  same."  The  charter  then  proceeded  to 
incorporate  Dartmouth  College,  making  it  "  from  hence- 
forth and  forever  "  a  body  corporate  and  politic,  and  giving 
the  necessary  corporate  powers  to  carry  out  its  purpose  of 
instructing  and  educating  the  youth  of  the  Indian  tribes  as 
shall  appear  necessary  and  expedient  for  civilizing  and 
christianizing  children  of  pagans,  and  also  for  the  education 
of  English  youth  and  any  others,  including  the  power  to 
appoint  professors,  tutors  and  various  officers  usually  con- 
nected with  such  institutions,  and  to  grant  such  degrees  as 
were  usually  granted  in  either  of  the  universities,  or  any 
other  college  of  the  realm  of  Great  Britain.  The  officers, 
it  was  declared,  might  exercise  their  authority  "  as  fully  and 
freely  as  any  of  the  officers  and  ministers  in  our  universities 
or  colleges  in  our  realm  of  Great  Britain  lawfully  may  or 
ought  to  do."  Eleazer  Wheelock  was  recited  to  be  the 
founder  of  the  institution  and  was  appointed  its  first  presi- 
dent, with  power  to  appoint  his  successor,  who  might,  how- 
ever, be  removed  by  the  trustees.  It  was  made  the  duty  of 
the  president,  in  order  that  the  English  contributors  might 
"be  satisfied  that  their  liberalities  are  faithfully  disposed 
of,"  to  transmit  annually  to  the  Trustees  in  England  an 
account  of  the  disbursements  of  the  sums  which  he  should 
receive  from  the  donations  and  bequests  made  in  England. 
The  verdict  then  set  out  the  acceptance  of  the  charter,  and 
that  immediately  after  its  organization  the  corporation  re- 
ceived by  gift,  devise  and  otherwise  lands,  chattels  and 
money,  and  that  among  the  gifts  to  the  college  were  a  grant 


62  OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS  [606 

of  lands  from  the  State  of  Vermont,  in  1785,  and  two  from 
the  State  of  New  Hampshire,  in  1789  and  1807.  The 
amending  statutes  are  then  set  out  and  the  proceedings  in- 
volved in  the  action  at  hand  are  given,  as  we  have  already 
recited  them. 

From  this  statement  of  facts,  found  in  the  special  verdict, 
it  is  clear  that  the  purpose  was  to  incorporate  Moor's  In- 
dian Charity  School,  and  that  the  method  was  to  create  an 
incorporated  college  and  have  the  school  funds  transferred 
to  it ;  and  this  is  exactly  the  view  that  Marshall  takes  in  his 
opinion. 

Mr.  Shirley,  however,  endeavors  to  show  that  the  facts 
were  quite  different,  and  that  the  Chief  Justice  was  well 
aware  that  they  were.  His  argument  on  this  point  is,  of 
course,  based  wholly  on  facts  outside  the  record,  nor  is  it 
clear  that  Marshall  really  knew  of  them.  Nevertheless,  we 
have  endeavored  to  ascertain  their  importance,  assuming, 
for  the  sake  of  argument,  that  they  had  been  in  the  record. 

Mr.  Shirley  marshalls  the  evidence  and  argues  the  matter 
at  such  length4  that  it  will  be  impossible  for  us  to  do  any- 
thing more  than  to  state  our  conclusions,  reached  after  read- 
ing his  statement.  He  contends  that  Moor's  Indian  Charity 
School  and  the  college  were  always  regarded  as  separate 
institutions,  even  after  the  incorporation ;  that  all  the  funds 
had  been  raised,  prior  to  the  incorporation,  belonged  to  the 
school  and  were  never  given  to  the  college;  and  that  the 
first  gift  to  the  college  was  a  large  grant  of  land  made  by 
Governor  Wentworth,  in  behalf  of  the  Crown,  in  January, 
1770,  thus  making  the  foundation  of  the  institution  a  pub- 
lic one. 

What  Mr.  Shirley  does  show,  we  think,  is  that  the  origi- 
nal intention  (which  is  plainly  shown  in  the  preamble  to 
the  charter  already  set  out)  was  to  incorporate  the  charity 
school,  with  the  idea  that  it  would  eventually  broaden  its 
operations — hence  the  name  "  college  " ;  that  the  English 
trustees  did  not  take  kindly  to  these  doings  of  Dr.  Whee- 

*  Shirley,  The  Dartmouth  College  Causes,  p.  20  ff.,  p.  412  ff. 


607]  THE  DARTMOUTH  COLLEGE  CASE  63 

lock,  and  that  he,  therefore,  promised  that  the  school  funds 
should  be  kept  separate,  as  before,  and  that  the  president 
of  the  school  who,  he  said,  was  not  necessarily  the  president 
of  the  college,  should  have  the  sole  administration  of  the 
funds.  As  a  matter  of  fact,  the  school  funds  must  have 
been  given  to  the  college,  as  there  was  no  such  legal  person 
as  the  school,  and,  in  fact,  we  are  told  that  gifts,  which  had 
been  made  to  the  school  upon  condition  that  it  be  incorpor- 
ated, were  called  for  immediately  after  the  charter  was 
granted.  In  1807  we  find  the  legislature  passing  an  act 
which,  after  reciting  that  it  had  always  been  considered  that 
the  school  and  the  college  were  separate  branches  of  the 
same  institution,  with  separate  funds,  and  that  the  president 
of  the  college  "ever  has  been  and  ever  should  be"  presi- 
dent of  the  school,  but  that  the  trustees  had  never  consid- 
ered that  they  had  any  official  right  to  be  concerned  in  the 
application  of  the  funds  of  the  school,  proceeds  to  associate 
the  trustees  with  the  president  in  that  office.  It  is  perfectly 
clear,  therefore,  that,  legally,  there  never  had  been  more 
than  one  institution,  namely,  Dartmouth  College,  and  that 
Dr.  Wheelock  was  taking  an  impossible  position  when  he 
told  the  English  trustees  that  the  school  funds  were  con- 
trolled by  the  president  of  the  school,  who  was  not,  neces- 
sarily, president  of  the  college.  Mr.  Shirley  does  show, 
however,  that  one  of  the  first  gifts  to  the  college  was  a  large 
grant  of  land  by  the  Crown.  Litigation  threatened  to  arise 
later  over  the  right  of  the  Crown  to  make  this  grant,  and 
the  college  therefore  surrendered  it,  taking,  two  years  after- 
wards, in  1789,  the  grant  referred  to  in  the  special  verdict 
as  a  substitute  for  the  prior  doubtful  grant.  This  lends  a 
semblance  of  validity  to  the  claim  made  by  Mr.  Shirley  that 
the  foundation  was  a  public  one  in  the  sense  of  the  rule 
stated  in  Blackstone  that,  if  the  king  and  a  private  man  join 
in  endowing  an  eleemosynary  foundation,  "  here  the  king 
has  his  prerogative,"  and  therefore  "  the  king  alone  shall  be 
the  founder  of  it."5  It  would  seem  probable  that,  in  such 

5  Blackstone,  481. 


64  OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS  [608 

a  case,  the  king  would  have  had  the  visitatorial  power  to  the 
same  extent  as  a  private  founder,  and  that,  after  the  Revo- 
lution, this  power  might  be  said  to  have  become  vested  in 
the  state  legislature — though  in  the  case  of  so-called  "  civil " 
corporations,  of  which  the  king  was  always  considered  the 
founder,  it  was  laid  down  that  his  visitatorial  power  could 
only  be  exercised  by  the  court  of  King's  Bench.6  But  it 
would  be  a  question  for  serious  consideration  whether  the 
visitor  would  have  had  the  right  to  do  what  the  legislature 
had  attempted  to  do  in  the  case  of  Dartmouth  College. 

The  rules  relating  to  the  power  of  visitation  were  very 
technical,  but,  in  view  of  the  fact  that  the  charity  school 
was  already  founded  and  in  existence  and  that  the  charter 
was  intended  to  incorporate  this  school,  and  particularly,  in 
view  of  the  fact  that  Dr.  Wheelock  is  named  in  the  charter 
as  the  founder,  thus  evidencing  an  intention  on  the  part  of 
the  Crown  to  waive  its  prerogative  in  the  matter,  we  do  not 
think  the  argument  would  have  been  applicable  had  all  the 
facts  which  Mr.  Shirley  sets  out  appeared  in  the  record. 

Further  criticisms  of  the  statement  of  facts,  as,  for  in- 
stance, that  there  was  no  formal  application  such  as  was 
suggested  by  Marshall's  statement  that  there  was  an  "  appli- 
cation" made  for  a  charter,  are  not  of  enough  moment  to 
need  answering.  It  has  also  been  pointed  out  that  the 
power  of  giving  degrees  and  the  powers  of  the  officers  of 
the  college  were  recited  to  be  as  comprehensive  as  those  of 
the  universities  in  England,  with  the  object  of  proving  that 
the  College  was  really  a  university,  and  of  following  this 
up  by  showing  that  the  universities  were  public  corpora- 
tions. It  has  already  been  shown,  however,  that  there  was 
no  grand  division  of  corporations,  at  common  law,  into 
public  and  private. 

Having  considered  the  questions  which  have  arisen  from 
the  special  circumstances  surrounding  the  granting  of  this 
particular  charter,  it  remains  to  consider  the  fundamental 
question  of  the  case,  namely,  what  was  the  status  of  cor- 

6  i  Blackstone,  481. 


609]  THE  DARTMOUTH  COLLEGE  CASE  65 

porations  at  common  law  ?  Did  the  municipal  law  of  Eng- 
land regard  corporate  franchises  in  the  same  light  as  it 
regarded  other  kinds  of  property  ?  Can  these  grants  fairly 
be  said  to  have  been  considered  to  be  contracts,  according 
to  the  principles  of  the  common  law?  And  if  it  cannot 
quite  be  said  that,  upon  common  law  principles,  they  were 
contracts,  could  it  be  said  that  they  were  contracts  upon  the 
principles  of  natural  or  universal  law  ? 

The  fundamental  principles  of  the  law  of  corporations  as 
they  appear,  practically  unchanged,  during  the  latter  half 
of  the  eighteenth  and  the  first  half  of  the  nineteenth  cen- 
turies may  be  found  in  Blackstone's  Commentaries,  pub- 
lished in  1762;  in  Wooddeson's  Lectures  on  the  Laws  of 
England,  published  in  1783 ;  in  Kyd  on  Corporations,  pub- 
lished in  1793 ;  and  in  Grant  on  Corporations,  a  work  pub- 
lished somewhat  later  than  these  three  (1850),  yet  which 
contains,  practically  unaltered,  all  the  old  law  on  this  subject. 

Referring  to  these  authorities,  we  find  that,  as  between 
the  Crown  and  the  recipients  of  its  grants  of  corporate 
powers,  the  charter  became  a  private,  vested  right.  This 
plainly  appears  from  the  doctrines:  that  a  charter  is  of  no 
effect  until  it  is  accepted  by  the  incorporators ;  that  a  new 
or  amended  charter  is  not  effectual  until  it  is  accepted  by 
the  corporation  ;7  and  that  the  Crown  cannot  dissolve  a  cor- 
poration.8 Grant  says: 

The  general  principle  of  law  with  respect  to  grants  being  that  the 
Crown  cannot  derogate  from  its  own  grant,  it  follows  that  when  a 
charter  has  once  been  granted  and  accepted,  the  king  cannot  after- 
wards interfere  with  the  operations  of  the  provisions  of  it,  or  with 
the  privileges,  rights  and  liabilities  that  are  incident  to  a  corporation.9 

In  the  leading  case  of  The  King  v.  Passmore,10  Duller,  J. 
said: 

I  do  not  know  how  to  reason  on  this  point  better  than  in  the 
manner  urged  by  one  of  the  relator's  counsel,  who  considered  the 
grant  of  incorporation  to  be  a  compact  between  the  Crown  and  a 

7  Grant  on  Corporations,  pp.  18,  19. 

8  Ibid.,  p.  10 ;  i  Blackstone,  485. 
»  Grant,  p.  33- 

"  3  T.  R.  246. 

5 


66  OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS  [6lO 

certain  number  of  subjects,  the  latter  of  whom  undertake,  in  con- 
sideration of  the  privileges  which  are  bestowed,  to  exert  themselves 
for  the  good  government  of  the  place. 

Again,  it  may  be  pointed  out  that  a  corporation  is  spoken 
of  by  Blackstone  as  a  franchise.11  A  franchise,  moreover, 
is  classed  as  an  incorporeal  hereditament,  that  is,  as  prop- 
erty. The  whole  law  of  corporations  is  treated  by  Black- 
stone  and  other  writers  as  a  part  of  private  law.  Liberties, 
franchises  and  privileges  were  among  the  things  mentioned 
in  Magna  Charta,  of  which  a  freeman  should  not  be  dis- 
seized, but  by  the  judgment  of  his  peers  or  the  law  of  the 
land.12 

The  inference  is,  without  doubt,  clearly  and  strongly  war- 
ranted that  the  franchise  of  being  a  corporation  was  a  pri- 
vate, property  right,  and  that,  as  such,  it  was  regarded  as 
sacred,  as  much  guaranteed  against  parliamentary  confis- 
cation as  any  other  property  right  of  an  individual,  and 
hence,  upon  the  principles  of  natural  or  universal  law,  nay. 
even  upon  the  principles  of  the  common  law  itself,  could 
fairly  be  regarded  as  a  contract,  binding  upon  Parliament 
as  well  as  upon  the  Crown.  Clearly,  the  burden  is  shifted 
upon  him  who  would  prove  the  contrary. 

These  rules  of  the  common  law  seem  to  furnish  the  only 
solid  foundation  for  the  court's  decision,  yet  they  receive 
quite  varying  treatment  at  the  hands  of  the  three  Justices 
who  delivered  opinions  in  the  case.  Justice  Washington 
relies  on  these  rules  more  specifically  than  does  either  Story 
or  Marshall.  He  sets  them  out  in  full  to  prove  his  first 
point — that  a  corporate  charter  is  a  contract.  He  then 
draws  a  distinction  between  public  and  private  corporations, 
holding  that  the  former  are  subject  to  legislative  control 
whereas  the  latter  are  not.  A  college  he  finds  to  be  a  pri- 
vate eleemosynary  corporation. 

Washington,  apparently,  did  not  find  it  necessary  to  re- 
fute the  argument  that  Parliament  could  not  have  been 
obligated  by  its  contract  since  it  was  legally  omnipotent. 

11 2  Blackstone's  Corns.,  37. 
12  i  Coke's  Institutes,  47. 


6ll]  THE  DARTMOUTH  COLLEGE  CASE  67 

Story  does  not  place  any  particular  emphasis  upon  the 
specific  doctrines  which  Washington  relied  on.  He  begins 
by  describing  a  corporation  as  an  artificial  person,  existing 
in  contemplation  of  law,  etc.,  and  then  launches  into  a  dis- 
quisition upon  public  and  private  corporations.  He  reviews 
the  doctrines  as  to  the  visitatorial  powers  of  the  founders 
of  eleemosynary  corporations,  reviews  the  College  charter, 
and  determines  that  it  is  a  private  eleemosynary  corpora- 
tion. He  then  states,  page  683 : 

We  are  now  led  to  the  consideration  of  the  first  question  in  the 
cause,  whether  this  charter  is  a  contract  within  the  clause  of  the 
constitution  prohibiting  any  state  from  passing  any  law  impairing 
the  obligation  of  contracts, 

and,  after  stating  and  explaining  Fletcher  v.  Peck,  says : 

It  determines  in  the  most  unequivocal  manner,  that  the  grant  of  a 
State  is  a  contract  within  the  clause  of  the  constitution  now  in  ques- 
tion, and  that  it  implies  a  contract  not  to  reassume  the  rights 
granted.  A  fortiori,  the  doctrine  applies  to  a  charter  or  grant  from 
the  king. 

Continuing,  he  discusses  at  some  length  the  question  of 
consideration,  then  the  question — which  none  of  the  other 
justices  discussed — as  to  how  a  corporation  could  be  a  con- 
tracting party  to  the  sovereign  act  which  creates  it.  This 
he  follows  with  an  answer  to  the  criticism  that  there  could 
be  no  contract  between  the  State  and  the  trustees  because 
the  latter  had  no  private  beneficial  interest  in  the  property, 
a  point  which  he  treats  from  various  aspects  and  at  great 
length.  After  meeting  the  objection  that  the  charter  was 
dissolved  by  the  Revolution,  he  finishes  the  opinion  by  ex- 
amining the  acts  of  New  Hampshire  in  question  and  point- 
ing out  how  they  impaired  the  obligation  of  the  contract 
contained  in  the  original  charter,  and  here  he  brings  in  sev- 
eral of  the  rules  which  Washington  relied  on,  as,  for  ex- 
ample, that  a  new  charter  cannot  be  imposed  on  a  corpora- 
tion without  its  consent. 

Chief  Justice  Marshall  argues  quite  differently  from 
either  Story  or  Washington.  He  opens  the  argument  with 
this  assertion,  page  627 : 


68  OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS  [6 12 

It  can  require  no  argument  to  prove  that  the  circumstances  of  this 
case  constitute  a  contract.  An  application  is  mack  to  the  crown  for 
a  charter  to  incorporate  a  religious  and  literary  institution.  In  the 
application  it  is  stated  that  large  contributions  have  been  made  for 
the  object,  which  will  be  conferred  on  the  corporation  as  soon  as  it 
shall  be  created.  The  charter  is  granted,  and  on  its  faith  property 
is  conveyed.  Surely  in  this  transaction  every  ingredient  of  a  com- 
plete and  legitimate  contract  is  found. 

"  Is  this  contract  protected  by  the  constitution  of  the 
United  States  ? "  he  asks.  "  It  is  argued,"  he  says,  "  that 
the  clause  was  not  intended  to  restrain  the  States  from 
regulating  their  civil  institutions."  To  this  he  is  quite  ready 
to  agree.  Therefore  he  says,  pages  629,  630: 

This  is  the  point  on  which  the  cause  essentially  depends.  If  the 
act  of  incorporation  be  a  grant  of  political  power,  if  it  create  a 
civil  institution  to  be  employed  in  the  administration  of  government, 
or  if  the  funds  of  the  college  be  public  property,  or  if  the  State  of 
New  Hampshire,  as  a  government,  be  alone  interested  in  its  trans- 
actions, the  subject  is  one  in  which  the  legislature  may  act  according 
to  its  judgment,  unrestrained  by  any  limitation  of  its  power  imposed 
by  the  constitution  of  the  United  States. 

As  was  his  wont,  Marshall  cites  practically  no  authorities. 
He  examines  the  charter.  It  appears  to  be  a  private 
eleemosynary  corporation.  Do  its  objects  stamp  on  it  a 
different  character?  No;  every  schoolmaster  is  not  a 
public  officer.  Nor  does  the  source  from  which  it  derived 
its  funds  make  it  a  public  institution.  Is  it  from  the  act  of 
incorporation?  This  he  likewise  discusses  on  principle, 
until  he  asks  the  question :  "  Is  it  because  its  existence,  its 
capacities,  its  powers,  are  given  by  law?"  Because  the 
government  has  given  it  power  to  take  property  may  it  in- 
terfere to  direct  how  and  for  what  purposes  this  property 
may  be  held?  This  he  answers  by  asserting:  "This  prin- 
ciple has  never  been  asserted  or  recognized,  and  is  supported 
by  no  authority.  Can  it  derive  aid  from  reason?"  He 
then  enters  into  the  question,  which  he  thinks  the  most  diffi- 
cult, as  to  who  has  sufficient  interest  in  the  property  of  the 
College  to  give  him  a  standing  in  court.  In  so  doing  he 
makes  the  following  rather  interesting  remark,  page  643, 
in  regard  to  the  omnipotent  power  of  Parliament,  he  being 
the  only  justice  who  has  anything  to  say  upon  the  subject : 


6 1 3]  THE  DARTMOUTH  COLLEGE  CASE  69 

According  to  the  theory  of  the  British  Constitution,  their  Parlia- 
ment is  omnipotent.  To  annul  corporate  rights  might  give  a  shock 
to  public  opinion,  which  that  government  has  chosen  to  avoid;  but 
its  power  is  not  questioned.  Had  Parliament,  immediately  after  the 
emanation  of  this  charter,  and  the  execution  of  those  conveyances 
which  followed  it,  annulled  the  instrument,  so  that  the  living  donors 
would  have  witnessed  the  disappointment  of  their  hopes,  the  perfidy 
of  the  transaction  would  have  been  universally  acknowledged.  Yet, 
then,  as  now,  the  donors  would  have  had  no  interest  in  the  property ; 
then,  as  now,  those  who  might  be  students  would  have  had  no  rights 
to  be  violated;  then,  as  now,  it  might  be  said,  that  the  trustees,  in 
whom  the  rights  of  all  were  combined,  possessed  no  private,  indi- 
vidual, beneficial  interest  in  the  property  confided  to  their  protec- 
tion. Yet  the  contract  would  at  that  time  have  been  deemed  sacred 
by  all.  What  has  since  occurred  to  strip  it  of  its  inviolability? 
Circumstances  have  not  changed.  In  reason,  in  justice,  and  in  law, 
it  is  now  what  it  was  in  1769. 

He  concludes  this  part  of  the  argument  by  saying,  page 
643 :  "  This  is  plainly  a  contract  to  which  the  donors,  the 
trustees,  and  the  crown  (to  whose  rights  and  obligations 
New  Hampshire  succeeds)  were  the  original  parties.  It  is 
a  contract  made  on  a  valuable  consideration.  It  is  a  con- 
tract for  the  security  and  disposition  of  property.  It  is  a 
contract,  on  the  faith  of  which  real  and  personal  estate  has 
been  conveyed  to  the  corporation." 

"  It  is  more  than  possible,"  he  admits,  "  that  the  preserva- 
tion of  rights  of  this  description  was  not  particularly  in  the 
view  of  the  framers  of  the  constitution."  Being  within  the 
words  of  the  Constitution,  however,  it  must  be  within  its 
operation  likewise,  "unless  there  be  something  in  the  literal 
construction  so  obviously  absurd,  or  mischievous,  or  repug- 
nant to  the  general  spirit  of  the  instrument,  as  to  justify 
those  who  expound  the  constitution  in  making  it  an  excep- 
tion." But  he  finds  that  public  policy  does  not  demand  that 
these  institutions  remain  subject  to  legislative  supervision. 

The  charter  was  therefore  a  contract  protected  by  the 
United  States  Constitution.  New  Hampshire  succeeded  to 
the  obligations  of  the  Crown.  And  here  he  again  touches 
upon  the  omnipotent  power  of  Parliament.  He  says,  page 
651: 

By  the  revolution,  the  duties,  as  well  as  the  powers  of  govern- 
ment devolved  on  the  people  of  New  Hampshire.  It  is  admitted, 


7O  OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS  [614 

that  among  the  latter  was  comprehended  the  transcendent  power  of 
parliament,  as  well  as  that  of  the  executive  department.  It  is  too 
clear  to  require  the  support  of  argument,  that  all  contracts  and 
rights,  respecting  property,  remain  unchanged  by  the  revolution. 
The  obligations,  then,  which  were  created  by  the  charter  of  Dart- 
mouth College,  were  the  same  in  the  new  that  they  had  been  in  the 
old  government.  The  power  of  the  government  was  also  the  same. 
A  repeal  of  this  charter  at  any  time  prior  to  the  adoption  of  the 
present  constitution  of  the  United  States  would  have  been  an  extra- 
ordinary and  unprecedented  act  of  power,  but  one  which  could  have 
been  contested  only  by  the  restrictions  upon  the  legislature  to  be 
found  in  the  constitution  of  the  State.  But  the  constitution  of  the 
United  States  has  imposed  this  additional  limitation,  that  the  legis- 
lature of  a  State  shall  pass  no  act  impairing  the  obligation  of 
contracts. 

The  opinion  ends  with  a  demonstration  that  the  acts  of 
New  Hampshire  impaired  the  obligation  of  the  contract. 

The  foregoing  is,  of  course,  but  a  bare  outline  of  the 
arguments,  and  can  give  only  an  inadequate  idea  of  Story's 
painstaking  and  exhaustive  citation  of  authorities  and  of 
the  exquisitely  polished  and  effective  argument  of  Marshall. 

Marshall  argued  upon  principle,  not  upon  authority,  and, 
as  such,  the  argument  is  a  very  powerful  one.  The  prop- 
erty donated  to  this  college  should  not  belong,  he  feels, 
either  in  justice  or  upon  the  ground  of  public  policy,  to  the 
state;  it  is  private  property.  But  to  allow  the  legislature 
to  dissolve  the  corporation  at  its  pleasure  would  work  a  for- 
feiture of  this  property. 

In  spite  of  the  force  of  this  reasoning,  it  seems  that  the 
question,  how  did  the  common  law  and  the  constitutional 
practice  of  England  regard  corporations,  has  such  a  direct 
bearing  upon  the  issue  raised  in  this  case,  even  though  the 
existence  and  obligation  of  the  contract  was  to  be  deter- 
mined upon  principles  of  natural  law,  that  more  attention 
should  have  been  paid  to  this  point  and  a  fuller  citation  of 
authorities  should  have  been  given  by  the  Chief  Justice. 
Granted,  however,  that  the  common  law  regarded  corporate 
franchises  as  private  property,  similar  in  kind  to  other  prop- 
erty, his  attitude  towards  the  omnipotent  power  of  Parlia- 
ment seems,  for  the  reasons  already  explained,  properly 
taken. 


6 1  5]  THE  DARTMOUTH  COLLEGE  CASE  7 1 

We  are  brought  back  therefore  to  the  question,  how  were 
corporations  regarded  at  common  law?  And  we  would 
again  call  to  mind  the  rules  that  the  Crown  could  not  alter 
or  repeal  a  grant  of  corporate  powers,  and  that  such  grants 
were  called  franchises,  which  were  incorporeal  heredita- 
ments, which  were  a  species  of  private  property. 

It  is  said,  however,  that  these  doctrines  only  demonstrate 
the  existence  of  a  contract  between  the  grantees  and  the 
Crown,  and  not  the  exisence  of  one  between  the  grantees  and 
Parliament.  It  is  true,  of  course,  that  a  contract  obligatory 
upon  the  Crown  only  is  proved;  yet  the  fact  that  it  was 
obligatory  upon  the  Crown  would  suggest  that  it  was  not 
considered  to  be  at  the  mercy  of  Parliament,  and  this  is 
strengthened,  as  was  said  before,  by  the  fact  that  franchises 
were  spoken  of  as  property.  However,  it  is  pointed  out  by 
Mr.  Hill13  that  the  common  law  writers  especially  recognized 
the  power  of  Parliament  to  dissolve  eorporations.  Cor- 
porations, he  says,  were  political  institutions  as  their  very 
name  (body  politic  and  corporate)  shows. 

Kyd  and  Blackstone  did  seem  to  consider  it  necessary  to 
assert  that  corporations  could  be  dissolved  by  an  act  of  Par- 
liament. If  by  this  they  meant  merely  that  Parliament 
could  dissolve  a  corporation  by  virtue  of  its  omnipotence 
solely,  it  does  not  affect  our  argument.  If,  on  the  other 
hand,  they  meant  that  Parliament  had  a  special  supervisory 
power  over  corporations,  it  strongly  negatives  the  contract 
theory.  Blackstone's  statement  rather  infers  the  one  view, 
Kyd's  the  other.  Blackstone  says :  "  A  corporation  may  be 
dissolved  by  act  of  Parliament,  which  is  boundless  in  its 
operations."14  Kyd  says,  "  That  a  corporation  may  be  dis- 
solved by  act  of  Parliament  is  a  consequence  of  the  omnipo- 
tence of  that  body  in  all  matters  of  political  institution."15 
Kyd,  it  may  be  said,  is  a  writer  who  displays  a  good  deal  of 
originality,  and  many  of  whose  theories,  therefore,  are  at 

13  8  American  Law  Rev.  189. 

14  i  Blackstone,  485. 

15  2  Kyd,  Corporations,  p.  447. 


72  OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS  [6 1 6 

variance  with  the  accepted  doctrines  of  that  time.  Thus  he 
maintains  that  a  corporation  is  not  a  mere  invisible  and  in- 
tangible body  existing  only  in  contemplation  of  law,  thus 
foreshadowing  the  newer  theories  on  the  subject,  and  also 
that  it  is  not  proper  to  speak  of  a  charter  as  a  franchise. 
The  latter  position  was  only  adopted,  however,  upon  the 
ground  that  a  corporation  was  a  person  in  itself,  whereas  a 
franchise  was  a  transferable  privilege  existing  only  in  the 
hands  of  some  person — a  corporation  "  is  to  a  franchise 
as  a  substance  to  its  attribute  " — but,  he  says  of  the  right  of 
the  members  of  the  corporation  to  act  in  that  capacity :  "  It 
is  a  right  of  such  nature  that  every  member,  separately  con- 
sidered, has  a  free-hold  in  it,  and  all,  jointly  considered, 
have  an  inheritance  which  may  go  in  succession.  Natural 
persons,  as  such,  are  capable  of  taking  and  holding  this 
right,  which  is  not  taken  or  held  in  their  politic,  but  in  their 
natural  capacity."16 

Besides  the  arguments  which  we  have  thus  far  consid- 
ered, much  stress  was  laid,  in  all  three  opinions,  upon  the 
fact  that  the  college  was  a  private  corporation.  This  im- 
plied an  admission  that  public  corporations  were  subject  to 
governmental  regulation  and  control,  and  a  claim  that  pri- 
vate corporations  were  not.  If  such  a  broad  distinction 
was  recognized  at  common  law,  the  case  is  certainly  proved 
in  favor  of  the  sanctity  of  the  corporate  rights  of  all  private 
corporations. 

This  argument,  it  may  be  noted,  was  not  treated  in  ex- 
actly the  same  way  in  all  of  the  opinions.  Marshall,  for 
instance,  did  not  claim  that  this  distinction  was  recognized 
at  common  law.  He  simply  said  that  the  Constitution  never 
intended  to  prohibit  the  States  from  regulating  their  civil 
institutions.  He  further  argued  that  the  fact  of  incorpora- 
tion was  immaterial  in  determining  whether  an  institution 
was  or  was  not  a  public  or  civil  one:  "The  character  of 
civil  institutions  does  not  grow  out  of  their  incorporation, 
but  out  of  the  manner  in  which  they  are  formed,  and  the 

16  I  Kyd,  Corporations,  p.  15. 


6 1 7]  THE  DARTMOUTH  COLLEGE  CASE  73 

objects  for  which  they  are  created."  In  fact  he  did  not  use 
the  words  "public  corporation,"  as  distinguished  from  "  pri- 
vate corporations/'  at  all. 

Story  laid  the  greatest  stress  upon  the  distinction,  and  re- 
garded it,  apparently,  as  a  well  settled  rule  of  the  common 
law.  We  think,  however,  that  he  draws  the  distinction  far 
more  sharply  than  the  authorities  justified.  The  only  real 
authority  is  the  case  of  Phillips  v.  Bury,"  which  we  shall 
shortly  consider. 

Justice  Washington  seems  to  state  the  matter  with  emi- 
nent fairness.  He  quotes  the  language  of  Lord  Holt  in 
Phillips  v.  Bury  practically  verbatim.  In  the  original  case 
it  is  as  follows : 

And  that  we  may  the  better  apprehend  the  nature  of  a  visitor,  we 
are  to  consider  that  there  are  in  law  two  sorts  of  corporations  aggre- 
gate; such  as  are  for  public  government,  and  such  as  are  for  pri- 
vate charity.  Those  that  are  for  the  public  government  of  a  town, 
city,  nursery,  or  the  like,  being  for  public  advantage,  are  to  be 
governed  according  to  the  laws  of  the  land ;  if  they  make  any  par- 
ticular private  laws  and  constitutions,  the  validity  and  justice  of 
them  is  examinable  in  the  king's  courts ;  of  these  there  are  no  par- 
ticular private  founders,  and  consequently  no  particular  visitor.  .  .  . 
But  private  and  particular  corporations  for  charity,  founded  and 
endowed  by  private  persons,  are  subject  to  the  private  government 
of  those  who  erect  them ;  and,  therefore,  if  there  be  no  visitor  ap- 
pointed by  the  founder,  the  law  appoints  the  founder  and  his  heirs 
to  be  visitors,  who  are  to  proceed  and  act  according  to  the  particular 
laws  and  constitutions  assigned  them  by  the  founder. 

"  This  right  of  government  and  visitation,"  continues 
Justice  Washington,  "arises  from  the  property  which  the 
founder  had  in  the  lands  assigned  to  support  the  charity; 
and  as  he  is  the  author  of  the  charity,  the  law  invests  him 
with  the  necessary  power  of  inspecting  and  regulating  it. 
The  authorities  are  full  to  prove  that  a  college  is  a  private 
charity,  as  well  as  a  hospital,  and  that  there  is,  in  reality,  no 
difference  between  them  except  in  degree;  but  they  are 
within  the  same  reason,  and  both  eleemosynary.  These 
corporations,  civil  and  eleemosynary,  which  differ  from  each 
other  so  especially  in  their  nature  and  constitution,  may 
very  well  differ  in  matters  which  concern  their  rights  and 

"  2  T.  R.  352. 


74  OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS  [6 1 8 

privileges,  and  their  existence  and  subjection  to  govern- 
mental control."  He  then  endeavors  to  justify  the  distinc- 
tion, but  upon  reason  rather  than  upon  authority. 

It  is  noticeable  that  Washington  is  careful  and  conserva- 
tive in  his  statement  as  to  the  doctrine  of  public  and  private 
corporations,  and  there  was  good  reason  for  his  being  so. 
In  the  first  place,  the  authority  of  Phillips  v.  Bury  is  condi- 
tioned by  the  question  which  was  at  issue  in  that  case. 
There  the  court  was  dealing  with  the  doctrine  of  the  visi- 
tatorial power  over  corporations,  and  the  question  was 
whether  the  king's  courts  had  jurisdiction  to  review  the  ac- 
tion of  the  visitor  of  a  college  who  had  deprived  the  rector 
of  his  office.  Lord  Holt  held  that  they  had  no  such  power, 
and  distinguished  the  case  from  that  of  public  corporations, 
as  to  which  the  king's  courts  exercised  a  visitatorial  power. 
He  was  far  from  saying,  indeed  could  not  have  said,  that 
the  king  could  interfere  in  the  government  of  these  public 
corporations,  nor  did  he  say  that  Parliament  was  the  proper 
body  to  supervise  them.  As  Blackstone  put  it,  the  king  was 
the  founder  of  civil  corporations,  but  his  visitatorial  power 
over  them  was  only  exercised  through  the  king's  courts. 
We  agree,  therefore,  with  Mr.  Hill  that  Phillips  v.  Bury 
does  not  warrant  the  conclusion  which  Story  drew  from  it, 
and  that  it  does  not  of  itself  furnish  authority  for  the  gen- 
eral distinction  taken  by  the  court  between  public  and  pri- 
vate corporations.  In  the  next  place,  as  Mr.  Hill  points 
out,  neither  Hale,18  Kyd,  Blackstone,  Wooddeson,  Chitty19 
nor  Stephen20  draws  any  distinction  between  public  and  pri- 
vate corporations.  The  classification  is  always  into  aggre- 
gate and  sole,  ecclesiastical  and  law,  civil  and  eleemosynary. 
Finally,  it  may  be  pointed  out  that  the  very  case  most  relied 
upon  to  demonstrate  the  contractual  relation  between  the 
Crown  and  its  grantees,  growing  out  of  a  grant  of  corporate 
powers, — the  case  of  The  King  v.  Passmore — involved  the 

18  Hale,  Analysis  of  the  Law. 

19  Chitty  on  the  Prerogative. 

20  Stephen's  Commentaries  on  the  Laws  of  England. 


6 1 p]  THE  DARTMOUTH  COLLEGE  CASE  75 

charter  of  a  borough,  and  the  language  of  Buller,  J.,  here- 
tofore quoted,  was  spoken  of  this  charter.  In  fact,  the 
doctrines  that  the  Crown  could  not  interfere  with  a  charter 
once  granted,  and  that  charters  were  franchises,  applied  to 
borough  charters  as  well  as  to  the  charters  of  other  kinds 
of  corporations. 

This  seems  to  put  the  reasoning  of  the  court,  at  least  of 
Story  and  Washington,  in  a  rather  difficult  position.  It 
was  declared  that  public  corporations  had  no  contract  rights 
in  their  franchises,  but  that  private  corporations  did  have. 
Yet  the  very  precedents  cited  to  prove  that  the  charters  of 
private  corporations  were  regarded  as  private  property  ap- 
ply equally  to  public  corporations.  To  declare  that  all  char- 
ters were  irrepealable  and  unamendable  by  the  legislature 
was  an  impossibility,  in  view  of  the  established  practise  in 
this  country  giving  the  legislature  full  control  over  public 
or  municipal  corporations.  To  declare  that  all  corporations 
were  subject  to  legislative  control  would  have  necessitated 
an  affirmance  of  the  decision  of  the  New  Hampshire  court. 

It  seems  correct  to  say  that  the  common  law  did  not  draw 
the  clear  distinction  between  private  and  public  corporations 
which  Story  attributed  to  it;  all  corporations  were  treated 
as  of  the  same  genus  and  species.  But  as  between  the  two 
conceptions  of  public  institution  and  private  property,  it 
may  fairly  be  said  that  corporations  were  placed  in  the  latter 
class,  as  we  have  already  shown  in  part  and  shall  show  more 
fully  hereafter.  The  criticism  of  this  distinction  is,  there- 
fore, not  of  any  particular  importance. 

There  is  one  more  authoritative  source,  to  which  we  have 
not  yet  turned,  and  which,  as  we  have  already  noted,  is  of 
especial  importance,  in  a  state  whose  legislature  is  legally 
omnipotent,  in  estimating  the  nature  and  sanctity  of  private 
rights,  namely,  the  legislative  usage  in  regard  to  these  rights. 

The  actual  precedents  which  we  are  about  to  review  are 
not  entirely  clear.  They  lend  themselves  to  conflicting  in- 
terpretations. But  although  this  is  the  case,  it  nevertheless 
suggests  another  consideration  which  should  not  be  over- 


76  OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS  [62O 

looked.  The  question  to  which  we  are  seeking  an  answer 
is:  Were  corporate  franchises  private  property?  In  its 
last  analysis  this  depends,  in  a  state  where  the  legislature 
is  omnipotent,  upon  the  way  in  which  such  franchises  were 
generally  regarded  at  the  time  they  were  granted,  and  Jus- 
tice McKenna's  observation,  in  his  dissenting  opinion  in 
Blair  v.  Chicago,21  in  which  he  was  endeavoring  to  deter- 
mine the  true  construction  of  a  contract  made  by  one  of  the 
States,  that  "whatever  we  may  profess,  it  is  not  easy  to 
realize  the  conditions,  thoughts  and  purposes  of  another 
time,"  is  peculiarly  applicable  to  the  case  at  hand.  Mar- 
shall, Story  and  Washington  were  much  closer  to  the 
thought  and  feeling  of  the  common  law  of  the  eighteenth 
century  than  we  are  to-day,  and  there  is  a  reasonably  strong 
presumption  that  they  interpreted  its  spirit  correctly  in  this 
instance. 

Judge  Bartlett,  in  his  very  able  argument  before  the  Court 
of  Appeals  of  New  Hampshire,  maintained  that  corpora- 
tions had  always  been  regarded  as  subject  to  regulation  by 
Parliament,  as  was  shown,  he  said,  by  actual  precedents.22 
Bartlett  argues : 

When  the  nation  was  dissatisfied  with  the  operations  of  the  land 
bank  and  south-sea  scheme,  no  difficulty  existed  for  want  of  power 
in  parliament  to  take  away  their  charters  and  even  make  the  mem- 
bers individually  liable  for  bills.23  In  the  time  of  Henry  Sixth  a 
statute  was  passed  by  which  all  corporations  and  licenses  granted 
by  that  prince  were  declared  to  be  void.24  Monopolies  granted  by 
charter  are  always  abolished  by  parliament  when  thought  proper.26 
So  the  fee  for  admission  into  trading  companies  is  altered  almost 
yearly  by  parliament,  although  much  against  the  inclination  of  the 
corporators;  as  also  the  qualifications  and  number  of  members. — In 
the  23rd  of  Geo.  II.  a  corporation  was  established  for  trade  to 
Africa,  with  great  detail  in  its  rights,  privileges,  etc.  and  by  statute 
the  fort  of  Senegal  with  all  its  dependencies  had  been  vested  in  it; 

21  201  U.  S.  401  at  501. 

22  This  point,  so  far  as  appears  from  the  printed  report,  was  barely 
touched  upon  in  the  Supreme  Court.    The  argument  for  the  new 
trustees,  which  was  made  in  that  court  by  different  counsel,  was,  it 
must  be  admitted,  far  inferior  to  the  arguments  presented  for  the 
same  side  in  the  court  below. 

28  5  Rus.  Mod,  Eu.  14. 
2*  Bac.  Abr.  Stat.  F.  18. 
25  i  Tm.  W.  M.  181. 


62 1  ]  THE  DARTMOUTH  COLLEGE  CASE  77 

still  in  the  5th  of  Geo.  III.  parliament  thought  proper,  on  much  de- 
liberation and  after  much  opposition,  to  take  from  their  jurisdiction 
that  fort  and  a  large  extent  of  coast,  vest  it  in  the  crown  and  declare 
the  trade  thither  free  to  all  his  majesty's  subjects. — Indeed  for  proof 
that  parliament  have  cont'rouled,  altered,  and  even  abolished  corpora- 
tions at  their  pleasure,  it  cannot  be  necessary  to  refer  to  particular 
cases,  while  no  book  upon  the  subject  can  be  found  that  does  not 
recognize  the  principle.28  But  if  examples  of  a  college  are  neces- 
sary, among  many  others,  that  of  Manchester  college  may  be  no- 
ticed, where  parliament  took  from  a  special  visitor  the  power  of 
visitation  and  vested  it  in  the  crown  by  the  2d  of  Geo.  II.27  Also 
the  case  of  Rex  &  Reg.  vs.  St.  John's  College,  where  by  statute  of 
i  W.  &  M.  for  abrogating  the  oaths  of  allegiance  and  supremacy,  it 
was  provided  that  the  office  of  head  or  fellow  of  a  college  in  either 
university  should  be  vacated  if  the  incumbent  refused  the  new  oath.28 

In  this  country  too  our  provincial  assemblies  exercised  the  same 
power  and  often  changed  the  whole  organization  of  such  institu- 
tions.— An  act  was  passed  in  Connecticut  in  1723  without  petition 
or  consent  of  the  corporation  " For  the  more  full  and  complete  estab- 
lishment of  Yale  College,  and  for  enlarging  its  powers  and  privi- 
leges." By  this  act,  the  number  of  trustees  was  enlarged,  new  offices 
created,  and  new  regulations  made  with  regard  to  the  number  which 
should  constitute  a  quorum.20 

By  an  order  of  the  general  court  of  the  province  of  Massachusetts, 
1673,  an  addition  was  made  to  the  members  of  the  corporation  of 
Harvard  College,  against  the  will  of  the  corporation.30  In  1784,  the 
charter  of  Trinity  church  in  New  York,  with  regard  to  induction 
was  repealed  by  the  legislature.31  To  these  might  be  added  many 
other  instances,  (as  3  John.  Rep.  127-151,  &c.)  But  I  will  here 
leave  the  question  as  to  the  subjection  of  corporations  to  the  gen- 
eral legislative  power  with  an  offer  to  abandon  the  defence  when 
one  unequivocal  authority  shall  be  produced  -by  the  plaintiffs  to  show 
that  the  exercise  of  such  power  by  the  legislature  of  Great  Britain 
was  ever  adjudged  illegal.32 

With  the  exception  of  the  South  Sea  Company,  the  other 
"  bubble "  companies  were  not  corporations  at  all.  The 
Bubble  Act  passed  by  Parliament  was  for  the  suppression 
of  all  those  pretending  to  act  as  a  corporation;  and  the 
South  Sea  Company  was  especially  excepted  from  its  pro- 
visions.33 The  statute  of  Henry  VI  referred  to  is  indeed 
mentioned  in  several  reported  cases,  but  an  examination  of 

26  2  Term.  Rep.  533—8  Term.  Rep.  430— Doug.  Rep.  637. 

27  4  Term  Rep.  236-237,  244;  2  Term  Rep.  318. 

28  4  Mod.  Rep.  233. 

29  2  Doug.  Summary,  183. 

30  i  Hutch.  Hist.  159. 
31 9  Johns.  Rep.  127. 

32  65  New  Hampshire  Rep.  573-574. 

83  Carr,  the  Law  of  Corporations,  p.  108 ;  Select  Charters  of  Trad- 
ing Companies,  vol.  xxviii,  Selden  Society  Publications,  p.  cxxxi. 


?8  OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS  [622 

the  statutes  has  failed  to  disclose  it.34  The  act  of  2  Henry 
VI,  chap,  i,  confirmed  all  existing  franchises.  The  argu- 
ment as  to  monopolies  is  not  in  point,  the  charter  in  ques- 
tion not  being  a  monopoly.  The  case  of  the  African  Com- 
pany seems  to  be  a  misleading  citation.  This  company 
seemed  to  have  no  private  right  in  the  forts.35 

The  case  of  Manchester  College  is  not  in  point  because 
the  act  of  Parliament  was  in  this  case  passed  to  avoid  the 
difficulty  of  a  vacancy  in  the  office  of  rector  caused  by  the 
disqualification  of  the  incumbent.  The  oath  referred  to 
which  was  required  of  heads  and  fellows  of  colleges  was 
merely  a  general  oath  of  allegiance  such  as  might  have  been 
required  of  every  person.  As  to  the  precedent  with  regard 

34  The  Statute  is  referred  to  in  these  cases  as  a  private  statute,  and 
possibly  for  that  reason  it  is  not  found  in  the  Statutes  of  the  Realm. 

85  The  corporation  which  was  divested  of  the  forts  was  the  suc- 
cessor of  the  Royal  African  Company  of  England,  but  it  was  a  cor- 
poration of  a  very  peculiar  nature.  The  act  of  25  George  II,  chap, 
xl,  which  repealed  the  charter  of  the  Royal  African  Company,  which 
had  gotten  into  financial  difficulties,  recited  that  that  company  was 
willing  to  surrender  its  lands,  forts,  cannon,  etc.  and  its  charter,  and 
appropriated  about  ninety  thousand  pounds  towards  paying  the  credi- 
tors of  the  company  and  about  twenty-three  thousand  pounds  as  a 
payment  to  the  owners  of  the  stock.  The  new  company  was  named 
The  Company  of  Merchants  Trading  in  Africa.  It  was  a  non-stock 
company.  Any  merchant  trading  in  Africa  could  become  a  member 
by  paying  forty  shillings.  It  could  not  trade  in  its  corporate  capac- 
ity. The  managing  committee  of  the  company  was  subject  to  the 
supervision  of  the  government  commissioners  for  trade  who  could 
remove  the  committee  members,  and  the  committee  had  to  submit 
annual  accounts  to  the  Exchequer  and  to  Parliament.  Finally  the 
forts  and  settlements  were  given  to  the  Company  not  for  its  own 
proper  use  and  behoof,  but  "  to  the  interest  and  purpose  that  said 
forts,  settlements  and  premises  shall  be  employed  at  all  times  here- 
after, only  for  the  protection,  encouragement  and  defense  of  said 
trade."  The  repealing  act  of  5  George  III,  chap,  xliv,  recites  this 
purpose  and  declares  that  it  will  be  better  fulfilled  by  vesting  the 
forts  in  the  Crown.  The  Royal  African  Company  had  been  given 
an  exclusive  grant  for  a  certain  period.  "  When  this  period  ex- 
pired," says  Mr.  Carr,  "  the  House  resolved  that  the  trade  ought'  to 
be  free,  that  forts  and  settlements  ought  to  be  enlarged  and  main- 
tained by  a  charge  borne  out  of  the  trade,  that  the  plantations  must 
be  sufficiently  supplied  with  negroes  at  reasonable  rates,  and  that  a 
large  stock  was  necessary.  The  company  protested  its  legal  right  in 
the  forts  under  a  grant  from  the  Crown,  and  the  threatened  Bill  did 
not  pass."  (Selden  Society,  Publications,  vol.  xviii,  Select  Charters 
of  Trading  Companies,  Introduction,  p.  48.)  This  shows  the  differ- 
ence in  nature  between  the  two  companies. 


623]  THE  DARTMOUTH  COLLEGE  CASE  79 

to  Yale  College,  we  have  not  examined  the  reference  and 
are  not  able  to  comment,  except  to  say  that  the  college  is 
not  alleged  to  have  opposed  the  amendment.  A  reference 
to  Htttchinson's  History  of  Massachusetts  does  not  disclose 
that  the  amendment  to  the  charter  of  Harvard  College  was 
made  against  the  will  of  the  corporation,  nor  does  this  ele- 
ment appear  in  regard  to  the  amendment  of  the  charter  of 
Trinity  Church. 

Mr.  Sullivan,  arguing  for  the  same  side,  gave  the  follow- 
ing instances  of  legislative  interferences  with  chartered 
rights : 

The  legislatures  of  many  of  the  states,  perhaps  of  all  of  them, 
have  taken  from  private  corporations  some  of  their  rights  and  privi- 
leges, when  the  welfare  of  the  community  has  required  it.  In  this 
state  it  has  often  been  done. — The  New  Hampshire  Bank  made  some 
of  its  bills  payable  in  Philadelphia.  The  General  Court  passed  an 
act  declaring  that  after  a  certain  day  "  it  should  be  unlawful  for  any 
Banking  company  in  this  state,  by  themselves,  their  directors  or 
agents  to  issue  any  bank  bill  or  bank  note  payable  at  any  other  place, 
than  at  the  Bank  from  which  it  is  issued."36  Every  Banking  com- 
pany that  acted  in  violation  of  this  law,  was  subjected  to  a  penalty 
of  one  hundred  dollars  for  each  offence.  The  New  Hampshire  Bank 
had  a  right,  by  its  charter,  to  make  its  bills  payable  in  Philadelphia, 
or  New  York,  or  at  any  place  whatever.  The  act  prohibiting  this, 
was  an  alteration  of  its  charter,  as  much  as  if  it  had  been  entitled, 
an  act  to  alter  and  amend  the  charter  of  the  New  Hampshire  Bank. 
Yet  it  has  never  been  suggested,  that  the  legislature  had  not  power, 
by  the  constitution,  to  pass  the  law.  In  many  other  instances,  the 
General  Court  has  deprived  banks  of  rights  conferred  on  them,  and 
in  effect,  altered  their  charters.  By  an  act  passed  in  June,  i8o7,3r 
Banks  were  forbidden  to  issue  bills,  which  were  not  payable  on  de- 
mand and  to  bearer;  or  which  were  subject  to  any  condition.  Every 
Bank,  existing  in  the  state  at  the  time  when  this  law  was  passed,  had 
a  right  by  its  charter  to  make  its  bills  payable  at  a  future  day — to 
order — and  subject  to  conditions.  The  law,  depriving  Banks  of 
these  rights,  has  never  been  considered  as  repugnant  to  the  consti- 
tution. It  has  not  unfrequently  happened  that  the  legislatures  of 
those  states,  in  which  Banks  have  been  established,  have  prohibited 
their  passing  bills  under  certain  denominations.  Thus,  the  General 
Court  of  Massachusetts  in  June,  1799,  made  a  law,  that  no  Bank, 
incorporated  by  the  legislature  of  that  Commonwealth,  except  the 
Nantucket  Bank,  should  issue  any  notes  for  a  less  sum  than  five 
dollars.38  By  their  charters  they  had  a  right  to  issue  bills  of  any 
denomination.  This  law  deprived  them  of  that  right. 

The  General  Court  have  not  only  imposed  new  duties  on  Banks, 

39  State  Laws,  283. 

37  Ibid. 

38  Mass.  Laws,  884. 


8O  OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS  [624 

but  have  added  heavy  penalties,  to  enforce  the  performance  of  them. 
By  an  act,  passed  in  June,  1814,  the  directors  of  the  several  Banks 
in  this  state  are  obliged  to  make  returns  of  the  situation  of  their 
respective  Banks,  annually,  to  the  Governor  and  Council;  and  in 
case  of  neglect  or  refusal,  the  Banks  are  subjected  to  a  penalty  of 
one  thousand  dollars. 

The  General  Court  of  Massachusetts  passed  a  law,  by  which  all 
the  Banks  within  the  Commonwealth  were  subjected  to  a  penalty  of 
two  per  cent,  a  month,  on  the  amount  of  those  of  their  bills,  which 
should  not  be  paid,  when  presented  for  payment  An  action  was 
commenced  against  the  Penobscot  Bank  to  recover  the  amount  of 
certain  bills,  presented  for  payment,  but  which  were  not  paid;  and 
also  to  recover  two  per  cent,  a  month  on  that  amount.  It  was  con- 
tended on  the  part  of  the  Bank,  that  the  law  was  unconstitutional. 
But  the  Court  recognized  the  authority  of  the  legislature  to  make  it. 
It  was,  say  the  Court,  "  A  duty  incumbent  on  the  legislature  to  pass 
the  law,  and  this  the  rather,  as  these  corporations  derive  all  their 
powers  from  legislative  grants."38  In  this  case  the  Court  recognizes 
the  authority  of  the  legislature,  to  superintend  corporations  of  a  pri- 
vate nature,  and  to  impose  penalties  upon  them  for  not  performing 
those  duties,  the  neglect  of  which  produces  mischief  to  society. — 
They  hold,  that  as  these  corporations  derive  all  their  powers  from 
legislative  grants,  it  is  not  only  the  right',  but  the  duty  of  the  legis- 
lature to  see  that  the  Commonwealth  receives  no  detriment.40 

Practically  all  of  these  acts  were  general  acts  regulating 
particular  phases  of  the  banking  business,  and  none  of  them 
necessarily  impaired  any  charter  provision,  nor  is  it  at  all 
likely  that  they  did  so.  Again,  if  any  of  them  did  impair 
charter  grants,  it  is  not  apparent  that  they  were  ever  brought 
before  and  sustained  by  the  courts. 

Angell  and  Ames,  in  their  treatise  on  private  corporations, 
cite  the  case  of  the  dissolution  of  the  Knights  Templars  in 
the  reign  of  Edward  II.  It  appears  from  Kyd,  however, 
that  this  body  was  incorporated  by  the  Pope  and  had  been 
dissolved  by  one  of  his  successors  some  years  before  the  act 
of  17  Edward  II  was  passed  judging  that  the  Templars 
were  well  dissolved  and  conferring  the  property  of  the  order 
upon  the  Knights  of  St.  John.41 

A  precedent  which  cannot  be  evaded,  however,  is  the 
case  of  the  dissolution  of  the  monasteries  in  the  time  of 
Henry  VIII,  and  the  subsequent  confiscation  of  their  prop- 
erty. The  case  was  apparently  considered  a  very  excep- 

39  8  Mass.  Rep.  445. 

40  56  New  Hampshire  Reports,  pp.  506,  507,  508. 
41 2  Kyd,  Corporations,  p.  446. 


625]  THE  DARTMOUTH  COLLEGE  CASE  8 1 

tional  one,  and  could  hardly  have  been  regarded  as  furnish- 
ing a  precedent  for  ordinary  times.42 

A  second  case  of  interference  was  the  passage  of  the 
"Corporation  Act"  in  the  reign  of  Charles  II.  This  act 
"en joined  all  magistrates  and  persons  bearing  offices  of  trust 
in  corporations  to  swear  that  they  believed  it  unlawful,  on 
any  pretense  whatever  to  take  arms  against  the  king,  and 
that  they  abhorred  the  traitorous  position  of  bearing  arms 
by  his  authority  against  his  person  or  against  those  that  are 
commissioned  by  him.  They  were  also  to  renounce  all 
obligation  arising  out  of  the  oath  called  the  solemn  league 
and  covenant ;  in  case  of  refusal  to  be  immediately  removed 
from  office.  Those  elected  in  the  future  were,  in  addition 
to  the  same  oaths,  to  have  received  the  sacrament  within 
one  year  before  their  election  according  to  the  rites  of  the 
English  church."43  Yet  it  is  by  no  means  apparent  that  these 
two  cases  of  Parliamentary  interference  sufficed  to  estab- 

42  Thus  Hallam  writes  of  the  confiscation  of  the  property  of  the 
monasteries :  "  A  few  more  were  afterwards  extinguished  through 
his   (Woolsey's)   instigation;  and  thus  the  prejudice  against  inter- 
ference with  this  species  of  property  was  somewhat  worn  off,  and 
men's  minds  gradually  prepared  for  the  sweeping  confiscations  of 
Cromwell.    The  king  indeed  was  abundantly  willing  to  replenish  his 
exchequer  by  violent  means,  and  to  avenge  himself  on  those  who 
gainsayed   his   supremacy;   but    it   was   this    able   statesman   who, 
prompted  both  by  the  natural  appetite  of  ministers  for  the  subject's 
money,  and,  as  has  been  generally  surmised,  by  a  secret  partiality 
towards  the  Reformation,  devised  and  carried  on   with  complete 
success,  if  not  with  the  utmost  produce,  a  measure  of  no  inconsid- 
erable hasard  and)  difficulty.    For  such  it  surely  was,  under  a  system 
of  government  which  rested  so  much  on  antiquity,  and  in  spite  of 
the  peculiar  sacredness  which  the  English  attach  to  all   freehold 
property,  to  annihilate  so  many  prescriptive  baronial  tenures,  the 
possessors  whereof  composed  more  than  a  third  part  of  the  house 
of  lords,  and  to  subject  so  many  estates  which  the  law  had  rendered 
inalienable,  to  maxims  of  escheat  and  forfeiture  that  had  never  been 
help  applicable  to  their  tenure.    But  for  this  purpose  it  was  neces- 
sary, by  exposing  the  gross  corruptions  of  monasteries,  both   to 
intimidate  the  regular   clergy,   and   to   excite   popular   indignation 
against  them."    Hallam,  Constitutional  History  of  England,  vol.  i, 
pp.  70-71. 

43  Hallam,  Constitutional  History  of  England,  vol.  ii,  pp.  27-28. 
The  object  of  the  act  was  to  oust  the  dissenters  from  the  corpora- 
tion and  to  place  the  royalists  in  control. 

6 


82  OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS  [626 

lish  the  doctrine  that  corporations  had  no  private  rights  in 
their  franchises. 

There  is  a  rather  interesting  passage  to  be  found  in 
Browne's  Civil  and  Admiralty  Law,  published  in  1802. 
Browne  says :  "  Corporations  were  dissolved  at  Rome  by 
the  prince,  by  death,  by  surrender,  by  forfeiture.  So  with 
us,  corporations  may  be  dissolved  by  act  of  Parliament, 
whose  power  is  said  to  know  no  limits,  but  is  on  them  very 
sparingly  and  cautiously  exercised."44 

Turning  to  a  recent  writer  upon  the  origin  and  develop- 
ment of  corporations,  we  find  the  author  remarking  that 
"  the  body  of  principles  apparently  necessary  for  the  regu- 
lation of  their  relations  have  been  attached  to  the  main  body 
of  English  Law  by  means  of  fictions."  For  this  reason,  he 
explains,  the  historian  and  jurist  have  always  had  difficulty 
in  knowing  how  to  treat  them :  "  It  has  always  been  a  ques- 
tion whether  they  were  public  or  private  in  nature,  or 
whether  they  were  divisions  of  the  state  or  associations  of 
citizens — a  matter  of  importance  in  technical  analysis."45 
Further  he  says : 

The  maturity  of  the  conception  of  corporations  in  the  English  Law 
was  undoubtedly  facilitated  by  the  development  of  the  corporations 
themselves.  It  was  not  entirely  fortuitous  that  the  conception  of 
corporations  as  artificial  persons  was  nearly  coincidental  with  the 
completion  of  the  process  of  "  shrinkage "  of  corporations  from 
entire  communities  to  smaller  select  bodies  within  them.  The  close 
bodies  in  guilds  and  municipalities  were  crystallizing  during  the 
fourteenth  and  fifteenth  centuries.  It  was  when  they  ceased  to 
derive  their  life  from  the  communities  themselves  and  appeared  to 
enjoy  an  existence  independent  of  them,  not  in  harmony  with  them 
but  rather  in  opposition  and  contrast  to  them,  that  their  distinct  per- 
sonality emerged.  Moreover,  the  development  facilitated  the  sub- 
stitution of  the  private  for  the  public  view  that  might  be  expected 
to  be  taken  of  the  communities.  The  close  bodies  as  well  as  the 
rest  of  the  community  regarded  the  powers  reposed  in  them  largely 
as  sources  of  private  advantage ;  the  state  was  accordingly  much 
more  readily  inclined  to  assign  them  to  the  department  of  private 
law  than  to  that  of  public  law.  The  nearer  they  approached  the 
plane  of  private  persons  in  their  activity,  the  easier  it  was  for  the 
jurist's  imagination  to  impute  personality  to  them.46 

44  Browne,  Civil  and  Admiralty  Law,  p.  148. 

45  Davis,  Origin  and  Development  of  Corporations,  vol.  ii,  p.  239. 

46  Ibid.,  p.  294. 


627]  THE  DARTMOUTH  COLLEGE  CASE  83 

This,  it  may  be  observed,  was  spoken  concerning  the  bor- 
oughs. The  later  history  of  the  boroughs  and  the  state  of 
corruption  into  which  they  fell  is  well  known.  The  borough 
franchise  must  indeed  have  appeared  to  be  private  property 
when  it  was  possessed  by  a  close,  self-perpetuating  body  of 
men  within  the  larger  community  which  constituted  the 
borough  itself.  The  struggles  of  the  boroughs  against  the 
attacks  on  their  charters  made  by  Charles  II  and  James  II 
must  also  have  tended  to  intensify  feeling  of  proprietorship 
among  the  possessors  of  the  borough  franchises. 

There  is  perhaps  another  aspect  of  the  borough  fran- 
chises which  affords  better  evidence  of  their  proprietary 
nature.  Even  before  the  corporate  idea  was  clearly  formu- 
lated the  boroughs  possessed  many  franchises  obtained 
chiefly  by  charters  from  the  king.  These  franchises  were 
the  chief  earmarks  of  the  borough  and -they  were  largely 
political  in  their  nature — the  right  to  their  own  court,  to  the 
firma  burgi,  to  be  free  from  tolls,  etc.  But  at  the  time  of 
which  we  are  speaking,  society,  was  based  upon  the  feudal 
system.  The  land  was  full  of  franchises.  Political  and 
proprietary  rights  were  everywhere  commingled,  but  com- 
mingled in  such  a  way  that  the  proprietary  side  was  by  far 
the  more  conspicuous.  These  feudal  privileges  of  the  bor- 
oughs gave  the  king  a  good  deal  of  control  over  them,  yet 
even  the  king  did  not  claim  the  right  arbitrarily  to  despoil 
them  of  their  privileges.  And  the  king  in  those  times  was 
clothed  to  a  much  greater  degree  with  the  sovereign  power 
of  the  state  than  he  later  became,  when  the  power  of  Par- 
liament expanded  to  his  detriment.47  After  describing  the 
various  franchises  of  the  boroughs,  Pollock  and  Maitland 
continue :  "  Such  in  brief  were  the  main  franchises  that  the 
borough  enjoyed,  and  these  franchises,  some  or  all  of  them, 
made  the  borough  to  be  a  borough.  This  gave  the  king  a 
tight  hold  upon  the  townsfolk.  The  group  of  burgesses 
was  a  franchise-holder  in  a  land  full  of  franchise-holders, 
and  had  to  submit  to  the  rules  which  governed  the  other 

47  i  Pollock  v.  Mail-land's  History  of  English  Law,  2d  ed.,  p.  668. 


84  OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS  [628 

possessors  of  royal  rights.  It  might  lose  its  privileges  by 
abuse  or  non-use ;  it  might  lose  them  by  not  claiming  them 
before  the  justices  in  eyre,  though  in  this  case  a  moderate 
fine  would  procure  their  restoration." 

Tracing  the  development  of  the  corporate  idea,  Pollock 
and  Maitland  note  the  change  of  the  boroughs  into  some- 
thing bearing  the  resemblance  of  a  gild — the  phase  of  devel- 
opment upon  which  Mr.  Davis  laid  stress  in  the  passage  we 
have  quoted  above.  It  is  interesting  to  note  one  of  the 
causes  which  these  writers  give  for  this  change.  "  In  the 
great  boroughs,"  they  say,  "  large  sums  of  money  were  sub- 
scribed in  order  that  privileges  might  be  bought  from  the 
king,  and  the  subscribing  townsfolk  naturally  conceived  that 
they  purchased  those  privileges  for  themselves.  Some  defi- 
nition of  the  privileged,  the  f  ranchised,  body  was  necessary, 
and  yet  in  the  great  boroughs  that  body  could  not  assume 
any  of  the  old  accustomed  forms.48 

It  would  seem  that  it  was  this  feeling  of  the  proprietary 
nature  of  the  borough  franchises  which  preserved  the  bor- 
oughs untouched  until  long  after  their  usefulness  had  ceased 
and,  indeed,  until  long  after  their  corruption  was  a  matter 
of  general  recognition,  for  it  was  not  until  1835,  sixteen 
years  after  the  decision  in  the  Dartmouth  College  case,  that 
their  reform  was  actually  accomplished. 

There  are  some  who  have  commented  upon  the  College 
case  who  have  used  the  argument  that  the  court  decided  the 
controversy  upon  musty  old  English  precedents  rather  than 
upon  the  liberal  principles  which  inspired  the  common  law 
upon  its  transplantation  to  this  country.  They  claim  that 
the  existence  of  special  privileges  of  any  kind  was  contrary 
to  the  genius  of  our  laws.  In  so  arguing  they  admit,  of 
course,  the  correctness  of  the  decision,  judged  by  English 
precedents.  Judge  Corwain,  of  the  Supreme  Court  of 
Ohio,  in  an  opinion  delivered  in  the  well  known  case  of 
Knoup  v.  Piqua  Bank,49  takes  this  position,  and  in  so  doing 

48  Ibid.,  p.  670. 

49  Decided  in  1850;  i  Ohio  St.  603,  616. 


629]  THE  DARTMOUTH  COLLEGE  CASE  85 

calls  attention  to  the  proprietary  nature  in  which  offices 
were  long  regarded  in  England.     He  says : 

It  is  plain  that  many  things  are  the  subject  of  a  franchise,  in  Eng- 
land, which  are  not  such  in  this  country.  The  best  illustration  of 
this  perhaps,  will  appear  by  comparing  the  nature  of  an  office  in 
England,  and  an  office  in  America.  An  office,  like  a  franchise,  is  a 
royal  gift.  It  is  considered  property,  in  England.  Some  offices  are 
estates  in  fee  simple,  or  fee  tail;  some  estates  for  life,  and  some 
only  estates  at  will.  Cruise's  Digest,  Volume  iii,  Title  25.  There 
are  some  offices,  also,  which  are  said  to  be  estates  for  a  term  of 
years,  or  for  one  year.  And  ministerial  offices  may  be  in  reversion, 
or  to  commence  at  a  future  period.  Some  offices  are  even  assignable 
by  deed.  But,  in  America,  an  officer  is  only  a  public  agent  or  trus- 
tee, and  has  no  proprietorship,  or  right  of  property,  in  his  office. 

Another  important  authority  which  has  been  a  good  deal 
cited — it  is  one  upon  which  Mr.  Hill,  in  the  article  hereto- 
fore referred  to,  lays  much  stress — is  the  argument  which 
Edmund  Burke  made  in  the  year  1783  upon  Mr.  Fox's  bill 
to  repeal  the  charter  of  the  East  India  Company.  The  bill 
was  not  passed  and  the  charter  therefore  was  not  repealed, 
and  so  was  in  full  force  at  the  time  the  College  case  was 
decided.  Mr.  Hill  contends,  however,  that  the  failure  of 
this  bill  to  pass  was  not  in  the  least  due  to  the  respect  enter- 
tained for  the  chartered  rights  of  the  company,  and  he 
maintains  that  the  argument  of  Burke  correctly  represents 
the  position  of  corporations  at  that  time.  Mr.  Hill's  quota- 
tion is  a  long  one,  but  it  necessitates  our  making  a  still 
longer  one,  for  the  reason  that  it  seems  that  there  is  a  quali- 
fying and  underlying  conservatism  in  this  argument  of 
Burke's  which  Mr.  Hill  does  not  see,  and  which  the  portions 
which  we  have  added  serve  to  emphasize. 

Webster,  in  his  argument  before  the  Supreme  Court,  had 
differentiated  the  case  of  the  East  India  Company  upon  the 
grounds  that  it  had  been  granted  the  widest  sort  of  political 
dominion  and  that  it  had  grossly  abused  its  privileges,  and 
these  distinctions  were  evidently  suggested  by  Burke's 
speech. 

Burke  argued  as  follows :  "  As  to  the  first  of  these  objec- 
tions ;  I  must  observe  that  the  phrase  of  the  chartered  rights 
of  men  is  full  of  affectation;  and  very  unusual  in  the  dis- 


86  OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS  [630 

cussion  of  privileges  conferred  by  charters  of  the  present 
description.  But  it  is  not  difficult  to  discover  what  end  that 
ambiguous  mode  of  expression  so  often  reiterated  is  meant 
to  answer."  He  proceeds  then  to  speak  of  the  natural 
rights  of  man.  These  are  indeed  sacred  things.  If  they 
are  further  affirmed  and  declared  by  express  covenants,  they 
are  in  a  still  better  condition ;  "  they  partake  not  only  of  the 
sanctity  of  the  object  so  secured,  but  of  that  public  faith 
itself  which  secures  an  object  of  such  importance."  And 
here  he  refers  to  Magna  Charta  and  similar  documents. 
"  These  charters,"  he  continues,  "  have  made  the  very  name 
of  the  charter  dear  to  every  Englishman.  But,  sir,  there 
may  be,  and  there  are  charters,  not  only  different  in  their 
nature,  but  formed  on  principles  the  very  reverse  of  those 
of  the  great  charter.  Of  this  kind  is  the  charter  of  the  East 
India  Company.  Magna  charta  is  a  charter  to  restrain 
power,  and  to  destroy  monopoly:  the  East  India  charter  is 
a  charter  to  establish  monopoly  and  to  create  power.  Po- 
litical power  and  commercial  monopoly  are  not  the  rights 
of  man ;  and  the  rights  to  them  derived  from  charters,  it  is 
fallacious  and  sophistical  to  call  the  chartered  rights  of 
men.  These  chartered  rights  (to  speak  of  such  charters 
and  their  effects  in  terms  of  the  greatest  possible  modera- 
tion) do  at  least  suspend  the  natural  rights  of  mankind  at 
large;  and  in  their  very  frame  and  constitution  are  liable 
to  fall  into  a  direct  violation  of  them." 

It  is  a  charter  of  the  latter  description  (that  is  to  say  a  charter 
of  power  and  monopoly)  which  is  affected  by  the  bill  before  you. 
The  bill,  Sir,  does,  without  question,  affect  it ;  it  does  affect  it  essen- 
tially and  substantially.  But  having  stated  to  you  of  what  descrip- 
tion the  chartered  rights  are  which  this  bill  touches,  I  feel  no  diffi- 
culty at  all  in  acknowledging  the  existence  of  those  chartered  rights 
in  their  fullest  extent.  They  belong  to  the  company  in  the  surest 
manner,  and  they  are  secured  to  that  body  by  every  sort  of  public 
sanction.  They  are  stamped  toy  the  faith  of  the  king;  they  are 
stamped  by  the  faith  of  parliament ;  they  have  been  bought  for  money ; 
for  money  honestly  and  fairly  paid;  they  have  been  bought  for 
valuable  consideration,  over  and  over  again. 

I  therefore  freely  admit1  to  the  East  India  Company  their  claim 
to  exclude  their  fellow  subjects  from  the  commerce  pf  half  the 
globe.  I  admit  their  claim  to  administer  an  annual  territorial  reve- 


631]  THE  DARTMOUTH  COLLEGE  CASE  8/ 

nue  of  seven  millions  sterling;  to  command  an  army  of  sixty  thou- 
sand men;  and  to  dispose  (under  the  control  of  a  sovereign,  imperial 
discretion,  and  with  the  due  observance  of  the  natural  and  local  law) 
of  the  lives  and  fortunes  of  thirty  millions  of  their  fellow  creatures. 
All  this  they  possess  by  charter,  and  by  acts  of  parliament  (in  my 
opinion)  without  a  shadow  of  controversy. 

Those  who  carry  the  rights  and  claims  of  the  company  the  furthest, 
do  not  contend  for  more  than  this;  and  all  this  I  freely  grant.  But 
granting  all  this,  they  must  grant  to  me,  in  my  turn,  that  all  polit- 
ical power  which  is  set  over  men,  and  that  all  privilege  claimed  or 
exercised  in  exclusion  of  them,  being  wholly  artificial,  and  for  so 
much  a  derogation  from  the  national  equality  of  mankind  at  large, 
ought  to  be  some  way  or  other  exercised  ultimately  for  their  benefit. 

If  this  be  true  with  regard  to  every  species  of  political  dominion, 
and  every  species  of  commercial  privilege,  none  of  which  can  be 
original,  self-derived  rights,  or  grants  for  the  mere  private  benefits 
of  the  holders,  then  such  rights,  or  privileges,  or  whatever  else  you 
choose  to  call  them,  are  all  in  the  strictest  sense  a  trust;  and  it  is 
of  the  very  essence  of  every  trust  to  be  rendered  accountable,  and 
even  totally  to  cease,  when  it  substantially  varies  from  the  purposes 
for  which  alone  it  could  have  a  lawful  existence. 

This,  I  conceive,  sir,  to  be  true  of  trusts  of  power  vested  in  the 
highest  hands,  and  of  such  as  seem  to  hold  of  no  human  creature. 
But  about  the  application  of  this  principle  to  subordinate,  derivative 
trusts,  I  do  not  see  how  a  controversy  can  be  maintained.  To  whom 
then  would  I  make  the  East  India  Company  accountable?  Why  to 
parliament,  to  be  sure,  to  parliament  from  which  their  trust  was 
derived,  to  parliament,  which  alone  is  capable  of  comprehending  the 
magnitude  of  its  object,  and  its  abuse,  and  alone  capable  of  an 
effective  remedy.  The  very  charter  which  is  held  out  to  exclude 
parliament  from  correcting  malversation  with  regard  to  the  high 
trust  vested  in  the  company  is  the  very  thing  which  at  once  gives  a 
title  and  imposes  a  duty  on  us  to  interfere  with  effect  wherever 
power  and  authority  originating  from  ourselves  are  perverted  from 
their  purposes,  and  become  instrument's  of  wrong  and  violence. 
That  the  power  notoriously,  grossly  abused  has  been  bought  from 
us  is  very  certain.  But  this  circumstance,  which  is  urged  against 
the  bill,  becomes  an  additional  motive  for  our  interference:  lest  we 
should  be  thought  to  have  sold  the  blood  of  millions  of  men  for  the 
base  consideration  of  money;  we  sold,  I  admit,  all  that  we  had  to 
sell,  that  is,  our  authority,  not  our  control.  We  had  not  a  right 
to  make  a  market  of  our  duties. 

I  ground  myself  therefore  on  this  principle — that  if  the  abuse  is 
proved,  the  contract  is  broken ;  and  we  reenter  into  all  our  rights ; 
that  is,  into  the  exercise  of  all  our  duties. 

Again  he  says : 

The  strong  admission  I  have  made  of  the  company's  rights  (I  am 
conscious  of  it)  binds  me  to  do  a  great  deal.  I  do  not  presume  to 
condemn  those  who  argue  a  priori,  against  the  propriety  of  leaving 
such  extensive  political  powers  in  the  hands  of  a  company  of  mer- 
chants. I  know  much  is,  and  much  more  may  be,  said  against  such 
a  system.  But  with  my  particular  ideas  and  sentiments,  I  cannot 
go  that  way  to  work.  I  feel  an  insuperable  reluctance  in  giving  my 


88  OBLIGATION  OF   CONTRACTS  [63  2 

hand  to  destroy  any  established  institution  of  government,  upon  a 
theory,  however  plausible  it  may  be.  ...  To  justify  us  in  taking  the 
administration  of  their  affairs  out  of  the  hands  of  the  East  India 
Company,  on  my  principles,  I  must  see  several  conditions,  ist,  The 
object  affected  by  the  abuse  should  be  great  and  important.  2nd, 
The  abuse  affecting  this  great  object  ought  to  be  a  great  abuse.  3rd, 
It  ought  to  be  habitual  and  not  accidental.  4th,  It  ought  to  be 
utterly  incurable  in  the  body  as  it  now  stands  constituted.  All  this 
ought  to  be  made  as  visible  to  me  as  the  light  of  the  sun  before  I 
should  strike  off  an  atom  of  their  charter.60 

It  thus  seems  that  Burke  was  far  from  asserting  that  the 
chartered  rights  of  the  company  were  held  at  the  good 
pleasure  of  Parliament.  When  he  says :  "  I  ground  myself 
on  this  principle — that  if  the  abuse  is  proved,  the  contract 
is  broken,"  he  admits  very  plainly  the  existence  of  a  con- 
tract between  Parliament  and  the  company.  If  it  is  con- 
tended that  this  contract  cannot,  under  his  theory,  be  a 
contract  upon  the  principles  of  municipal  law,  it  neverthe- 
less completely  meets  the  requirements  for  a  contract  upon 
the  principles  of  natural  law.  Upon  his  theory,  it  is  true, 
Parliament,  contrary  to  the  rule  laid  down  for  the  Crown, 
would  have  the  right  to  repeal  its  grants  when  they  were 
abused  without  having  to  appeal  to  the  courts  to  enforce  a 
forfeiture.  Such  a  doctrine  was  not,  however,  incompati- 
ble with  the  existence  of  a  contract  upon  principles  of  nat- 
ural law.  Moreover  it  could  not,  of  course,  have  been 
argued  that  Parliament  would  have  to  obtain  the  sanction 
of  the  courts  before  exercising  its  rights.  At  all  events, 
Burke  seems  to  recognize  enough  of  a  contract  to  warrant 
applying  the  prohibition  of  the  "contracts  clause"  to  it.51 

50Burke's  Works  (Boston,  1826),  vol.  ii,  p.  266  ff. 

51  We  might  note  that,  although  the  generally  accepted  doctrine 
in  this  country  seems  to  be  that  a  State  must  apply  to  the  courts  to 
have  a  forfeiture  of  chartered  franchises  enforced,  it  is  difficult  to 
see  why  a  legislative  act  repealing  misused  or  non-used  franchises 
should  be  denied  effect  by  the  courts,  if  the  fact  of  misuser  or  non- 
user  be  shown ;  that  is,  it  is  difficult  to  see  why  the  state  should  be 
compelled  to  go  through  the  proceeding  of  judicially  declaring  a 
forfeiture,  if  a  cause  for  forefeiture  actually  exists.  In  the  case  of 
Given  v.  Wright,  117  U.  S.  648,  the  court  said  that  they  could  see 
no  reason  why  the  government  could  not  take  the  benefit  of  the  pre- 
sumption of  the  surrender  of  a  franchise  by  its  non-user  for  a  period 
of  say  thirty  years  without  taking  judicial  proceedings  for  foref cit- 
ing the  same.  The  preponderance  of  the  evidence  seems  to  us  to  be 


633]  THE  DARTMOUTH  COLLEGE  CASE  89 

But  we  have  not  entirely  exhausted  the  authorities  which 
the  court  had,  or  might  have  had,  to  rely  upon,  and  we  wish 
to  complete  the  list  in  order  to  show  just  what  was  the 
strength  of  the  court's  position. 

In  1785  James  Wilson  published  an  argument,  which  he 
had  made  as  counsel,  in  opposition  to  the  repeal  by  the  legis- 
lature of  Pennsylvania  of  the  charter  which  a  prior  legisla- 
ture had  granted  to  the  Bank  of  North  America.  Although 
we  have  already  quoted  the  argument  at  length,  it  sets  out 
so  clearly  and  at  such  an  early  day  the  doctrine  that  a 
charter  was  a  contract  that  it  seems  worth  while  to  quote 
again  some  of  the  pertinent  language.  After  remarking 
that  generally  speaking  a  state  must  have  the  power  to  re- 
peal its  own  laws,  he  says : 

Very  different  is  the  case  with  regard  to  a  law  by  which  the  state 
grants  privileges  to  a  congregation  or  other  society.  Here  two 
parties  are  established,  and  two  distinct  interests  subsist.  Rules  of 
justice,  of  faith,  and  of  honor  must,  therefore,  be  established  be- 
tween them :  for  if  interest  alone  is  to  be  viewed,  the  congregation 
or  society  must  always  be  at  the  mercy  of  the  community.  .  .  .  For 
these  reasons,  whenever  the  objects  and  makers  of  a  instrument, 
passed  under  the  form  of  a  law,  are  not  the  same,  it  is  to  be  con- 
sidered as  a  compact  and  interpreted  according  to  the  rules  and 
maxims  by  which  compacts  are  governed.52 

And  James  Wilson,  the  reputed  author  of  the  "contracts 
clause,"  was  considered  one  of  the  most  learned  members 
of  the  Constitutional  Convention,  and  was  later  a  member  of 
the  Supreme  Court  of  the  United  States. 

Again,  in  an  early  Massachusetts  case,  the  following 
statement  was  made  by  Chief  Justice  Parsons :  "  We  are 
also  satisfied  that  the  rights  legally  vested  in  this,  or  in  any 

very  strongly  in  favor  of  the  view  that  the  common  law  regarded 
corporate  franchises  as  private  property  rights.  And  therefore  we 
think  it  may  fairly  be  said  that  a  charter  involved  a  contract  not  to 
repeal  it,  both  upon  common  law  principles  and  upon  natural  law 
principles.  And  if  the  common  law,  or  the  constitutional  practice 
of  the  period  under  discussion,  did  distinguish  between  public  and 
private  corporations,  and  between  the  security  with  which  they  held 
their  privileges,  we  think  it  safe  to  say  that  the  age  which  Dicey 
calls  that  of  "  Blackstonian  optimism "  and  "  Eldonian  toryism " 
would  not  have  repudiated  the  doctrines  as  to  private  corporations 
which  Marshall,  Story  and  Washington  attributed  to  it. 
62  Wilson's  Works,  ed.  Adrews,  p.  565. 


9O  OBLIGATION   OF   CONTRACTS  [634 

corporation,  cannot  be  controlled  or  destroyed  by  any  sub- 
sequent statute,  unless  a  power  for  that  purpose  be  reserved 
to  the  legislature  in  the  act  of  incorporation."53 

In  the  case  of  Terrett  v.  Taylor,54  decided  in  1815,  Justice 
Story  delivered  an  opinion  in  which  he  said  that  the  state 
legislatures  had  no  authority  to  repeal  the  charters  of  pri- 
vate corporations,  although  the  same  could  not  be  said  of 
public  corporations.  The  facts  of  the  case  are  peculiarly 
complicated,  and  we  shall  therefore  not  examine  them  here. 
It  will  suffice  to  say  that  it  is  a  very  close  question  whether 
the  remarks  of  Story  concerning  the  power  of  the  legisla- 
ture over  corporate  charters  were  or  were  not  obiter,  but 
the  probabilities  are  that  they  were  not.  The  case  came  up 
from  the  District  of  Columbia  and  involved  the  question  of 
the  effects  of  certain  acts  of  the  legislature  of  Virginia. 
Story,  therefore,  was  not  confined  to  the  "  contracts  clause  " 
as  the  sole  basis  for  the  decision.  Story  said : 

How  far  the  statute  of  1786,  ch.  12,  repealing  the  statute  of  1784, 
ch.  88,  incorporating  the  episcopal  churches,  _and  the  subsequent  stat- 
utes in  furtherance  thereof  of  1788,  ch.  47,  and  ch.  53,  were  consistent 
with1  the  principles  of  civil  right  or  the  constitution  of  Virginia,  is  a 
subject  of  much  delicacy,  and  perhaps  not  without  difficulty.  It  is 
observable,  however,  that  they  reserve  to  the  churches  all  their  cor- 
porate property,  and  authorize  the  appointment  of  trustees  to  man- 
age the  same.  A  private  corporation  created  by  the  legislature  may 
lose  its  franchise  by  a  misuser  or  a  nonuser  of  them ;  and  they  may 
be  assumed  by  the  government  under  a  judicial  judgment  upon  a 
quo  warranto  to  ascertain  and  enforce  the  forfeiture. — This  is  the 
common  law  of  the  land  and  is  a  tacit  condition  annexed  to  the 
creation  of  every  such  corporation.  Upon  a  change  of  government, 
too,  it  may  be  admitted  that  such  exclusive  privileges  attached  to  a 
private  corporation  as  are  inconsistent  with  the  new  government 
may  be  abolished.  In  respect,  also,  to  public  corporations,  which 
exist  only  for  public  purposes,  such  as  counties,  towns,  cities,  etc., 
the  legislature  may,  under  proper  limitations,  have  a  right  to  change, 
modify,  enlarge  or  restrain  them,  securing,  however,  the  property 
for  the  uses  of  those  for  whom  and  at  whose  expense  it  was  origi- 
nally purchased.  But  that  the  legislature  can  repeal  statutes  creating 
private  corporations,  or  confirming  to  them  property  already  ac- 
quired under  the  faith  of  previous  laws,  and  by  such  repeal  can  vest 
the  property  of  such  corporations  exclusively  in  the  state,  or  dispose 
of  the  same  to  such  purposes  as  they  may  please,  without  the  con- 
sent or  default  of  the  corporators,  we  are  not  prepared  to  admit; 
and  we  think  ourselves  standing  upon  the  principles  of  natural  jus- 

53  Wales  v.  Stetson,  2  Mass.  134  at  156.    1806. 
84  9  Cranch,  43. 


635]  THE  DARTMOUTH  COLLEGE  CASE  9 1 

tice,  upon  the  fundamental  laws  of  every  free  government,  upon  the 
spirit  and  the  letter  of  the  constitution  of  the  United  States,  and 
upon  the  decisions  of  most  respectable  judicial  tribunals  in  resisting 
such  a  doctrine.55 

Finally,  it  may  be  noticed  that  the  Court  of  Appeals  of 
New  Hampshire,  in  deciding  in  favor  of  the  new  trustees, 
rested  their  holding  solely  upon  the  ground  that  colleges 
were  public  corporations,  and  admitted  that  the  charter  of 
a  private  corporation  was  inviolable.  Again,  the  counsel 
for  the  new  trustees,  in  their  arguments  before  the  New 
Hampshire  court,  laid  far  more  stress  upon  the  point  that 
the  corporation  was  a  public  one  than  upon  the  point  that 
all  corporations  were  subject  to  governmental  control,  and 
in  the  Supreme  Court,  counsel  for  the  new  trustees  relied 
exclusively  upon  the  former  argument.56 

There  remains,  therefore,  to  be  considered  the  grounds 
upon  which  it  has  been  contended  that  Dartmouth  College 
should  have  been  classed  as  a  public  corporation.  The 
argument  of  the  Supreme  Court  of  New  Hampshire  upon 
this  point  is  based  almost  entirely  upon  the  proposition  that 
the  trustees  of  the  college  had  no  private  interest  which  they 
could  assert — surely  a  most  narrow  and  technical  method 
of  reasoning.  But  the  underlying  idea  of  the  opinion  rather 
clearly  appears  to  be  that  when  property  has  been  given  to 
found  institutions  such  as  colleges  and  hospitals,  the  donors 
loose  all  private  interest  in  the  property,  which  becomes 
subject  to  the  legal  control  of  the  state.  Although  disclaim- 
ing that  they  base  their  decision  in  the  slightest  degree  upon 
expediency,  the  court  devote  the  last  two  pages  of  the  opin- 
ion to  a  justification  of  their  position  from  the  standpoint 
of  public  policy.  And,  indeed,  the  argument  is  very  forci- 

55  9  Cranch,  51-52. 

56  The  New  Hampshire  court  said :  "  It  becomes,  then,  unneces- 
sary to  decide  in  this  case,  how  far  the  legislature  possesses  a  con- 
stitutional right  to  interfere  in  the  concerns  of  private  corporations. 
It  may  not,  however,  be  improper  to  remark,  that  it  would  be  diffi- 
cult to  find  a  satisfactory  reason  why  the  property  and  immunities 
of  such  corporations  should  not  stand,  in  this  respect,  on  the  same 
ground  with  the  property  and  immunities  of  individuals."    See  65 
N.  H.  Reps.  63^ 


92  OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS  [636 

bly  put,  and  in  a  style  which  Marshall  himself  could  hardly 
have  improved  upon. 

But  the  court  had  no  precedents  to  cite  upon  the  point 
that  the  trustees  had  no  rights  which  they  could  assert  in  a 
court  of  law.  After  all,  that  really  depended  upon  the 
question  whether  any  one  had  a  beneficial  interest  in  the 
property  which  they  could  have  asserted,  for,  if  there  was 
any  such  beneficiary,  surely  the  trustees  could  have  asserted 
his  rights  for  him. 

On  this  larger  question,  also,  we  think  it  rather  clear  that 
the  spirit  of  the  common  law  was  more  truly  interpreted  by 
the  Supreme  Court  of  the  United  States  than  by  that  of  the 
State.  The  state  court's  abstract  reasoning  to  the  effect 
that  property  given  for  these  public  purposes  becomes  essen- 
tially public  property  strikes  one  with  some  force  in  these 
times,  but  the  court  failed  to  cite  any  authorities  to  sustain 
its  contention.  Although  the  common  law  did  distinguish 
between  public  and  private  charities,  basing  the  distinction 
upon  the  inclusiveness  or  exclusiveness  of  the  designation 
of  the  cestuis  qui  trust,  it  continually  spoke,  as  we  have  seen 
from  Phillips  v.  Bury,  and  as  appears  from  other  cases,  of 
colleges  and  hospitals  as  private  eleemosynary  corporations, 
and  the  whole  law  as  to  founders  and  their  visitatorial  power 
is  strong  evidence  that  these  corporations,  whatever  others 
may  have  been,  were  regarded  as  private  in  their  nature. 
Then  again,  as  Chief  Justice  Doe  of  New  Hampshire  has 
pointed  out,  this  doctrine  would  have  to  be  applied  to  all 
charitable  trusts,  whether  they  are  incorporated  or  not ;  and 
yet  it  has  never  been  supposed  that  the  legislature  could 
appoint  trustees  of  its  own  to  administer  charitable  trusts 
or  associate  them  with  existing  trustees,  nor  have  our  legis- 
latures ever  undertaken  the  administration  of  charitable 
trusts.  This  has  always  been  left  to  the  judiciary.57 

It  is  arguable  that  public  educational  institutions  do  essen- 
tially belong  to  the  public  and  should  be  subject  to  public 
control,  and  the  opinion  of  the  New  Hampshire  court  is  an 

67  Harv.  Law  Rev.  16^-170. 


637]  THE  DARTMOUTH  COLLEGE  CASE  93 

excellent  example  of  such  an  argument;  but  nothing  is 
plainer  than  that  this  conception  has  not  yet  been  accepted 
by  the  law  of  this  country. 

The  contention  has  been  made  that  Dartmouth  College 
was  essentially  a  university,  and  that  universities,  as  dis- 
tinct from  colleges,  were  public  corporations.  Oxford  and 
Cambridge,  it  is  true,  were  regarded  as  somewhat  different 
in  their  nature  from  the  colleges  of  which  they  were  com- 
posed. They  were  civil  corporations,  whereas  the  colleges 
were  eleemosynary.  They  enjoyed  certain  political  powers, 
including  the  right  to  representation  in  Parliament,  but  as 
has  been  seen,  even  they  can  not  be  regarded  as  public  cor- 
porations at  common  law.  Also,  it  would  hardly  have  been 
proper  to  class  Dartmouth  College  as  a  university  merely 
because  it  had  been  given  the  power  of  awarding  degrees. 
It  had  none  of  the  other  powers  of  universities.  The 
clauses  in  its  charter  giving  its  officers  the  same  powers  as 
similar  officers  in  the  universities  of  England  can  hardly 
afford  the  foundation  for  any  inferences  as  to  its  character 
as  a  university  when  it  was  distinctly  designated  in  the  char- 
ter as  a  college.  This  argument  is  not  considered  by  any 
of  the  justices  of  the  Supreme  Court  in  their  opinions. 

We  have  endeavored  to  show,  in  the  first  part  of  this 
chapter,  that,  by  the  weight  of  authority  then  existing,  the 
ruling  of  Fletcher  v.  Peck  that  a  grant  was  a  contract  in- 
volving an  obligation  was  a  proper  ruling.  We  have  en- 
deavored to  show,  in  the  second  part  of  the  chapter,  that 
the  ruling  of  Fletcher  v.  Peck  that  a  state  was  bound  by  its 
grants,  was  also  consonant  with  the  generally  accepted  doc- 
trines of  that  day.  We  believe  that  these  conclusions  are 
fairly  supported  by  the  evidence,  but,  in  any  event,  these 
rulings,  whose  validity  we  have  been  discussing,  had  been 
fixed  in  our  law  by  Fletcher  v.  Peck  and  were  hence  estab- 
lished principles  by  the  time  that  Dartmouth  College  v. 
Woodward  came  up  for  decision.  If  grants  by  a  state  were 
contracts,  all  that  needed  to  be  done  in  the  College  case,  as 
Story  pointed  out,  was  to  find  out  whether  a  charter  was 


94  OBLIGATION   OF  CONTRACTS  [638 

considered  as  granting  a  private,  property  right.  We  have 
just  seen  that  there  was  a  preponderating  weight  of  author- 
ity to  support  the  affirmative  of  this  proposition. 

There  was  also  the  matter  of  the  omnipotent  power  of 
Parliament  to  be  considered.  It  would  not  seem  that  the 
mere  existence  of  an  omnipotent  power  should  have  or  did 
bother  the  counsel  for  the  college.  It  was  given  almost  no 
discussion  in  either  court.  Parliamentary  omnipotence  could 
repeal  a  land  grant  or  confiscate  a  man's  property,  yet  these 
proceedings  would  have  been  condemned  as  unlawful  and 
unconstitutional.  But  the  question  as  to  what  extent  this 
Parliamentary  omnipotence  actually  was  used  in  the  case 
of  corporations  did  have  a  very  important  bearing  upon  the 
nature  of  corporate  franchises,  that  is,  whether  they  were 
private  property.  The  second  question  therefore  tends  to 
merge  itself  into  the  first.  All  of  which  we  have  set  out 
more  fully  above. 

We  do  not  in  the  least  consider  that  the  case  should  have 
been  regarded  by  the  counsel  for  the  College  as  one  which 
they  were  sure  to  win.  While  we  say  that  the  preponder- 
ance of  authority  was  in  their  favor,  we  think  that  this  fact 
would  not  militate  against  a  feeling  on  the  part  of  counsel 
for  the  College  of  doubt  as  to  the  outcome,  and  a  desire  on 
their  part  to  bring  as  many  questions  as  possible  before  the 
Supreme  Court.  There  are  few  new  questions  of  law,  com- 
ing up  to  be  decided  for  the  first  time,  in  which,  if  there  is  a 
possibility  of  two  views  being  taken,  counsel  are  not  justified 
in  being  doubtful  as  to  the  outcome,  and  especially  if  the 
case,  like  the  present  one,  wears  somewhat  of  a  political 
aspect. 

Mr.  Shirley,  in  his  book  entitled  the  Dartmouth  College 
Causes,  has  come  to  conclusions  somewhat  at  variance  with 
those  which  we  have  reached.  We  wish,  therefore,  to  con- 
sider a  few  of  his  principal  conclusions  and  the  arguments 
by  which  they  are  supported.58  Mr.  Shirley's  argument  is 

58  Mr.  Shirley's  book  is  very  diffuse.  It  is  argumentative  almost 
from  cover  to  cover.  A  number  of  facts,  statements  and  cases  are 


639]  THE  DARTMOUTH  COLLEGE  CASE  95 

well  summarized  in  Lodge's  Life  of  Daniel  Webster,  from 
which  we  shall  quote.  Lodge's  conclusions  and  criticisms 
on  the  case  may  be  found  in  the  following  passages : 

It  now  becomes  necessary  to  state  briefly  the  points  at  issue  in  this 
case,  which  were  all  fully  argued1  by  the  counsel  on  both  sides.  Mr. 
Mason's  brief,  which  really  covered  the  whole  case,  was  that  the 
acts  of  the  Legislature  were  not'  obligatory,  i,  because  they  were  not 
within  the  general  scope  of  legislative  power;  2,  because  they  vio- 
lated certain  provisions  of  the  Constitution  of  New  Hampshire  re- 
straining legislative  power ;  3,  because  they  violated  the  Constitution 
of  the  United  States.  In  Farrar's  report  of  Mason's  speech,  twenty- 
three  pages  are  devoted  to  the  first  point,  eight'  to  the  second,  and 
six  to  the  third.  In  other  words,  the  third  point,  involving  the  great 
constitutional  doctrine  on  which  the  case  was  finally  decided  at 
Washington,  the  doctrine  that  the  Legislature,  by  its  acts,  had  im- 
paired the  obligation  of  a  contract,  was  passed  over  lightly.  In  so 
doing,  Mr.  Mason  was  not  alone.  Neither  he  nor  Judge  Smith  nor 
Mr.  Webster  nor  the  court  nor  the  counsel  on  the  other  side,  at- 
tached much  importance  to  this  point.  Curiously  enough,  the  theory 
had  been  originated  many  years  before,  by  Wheelock  himself,  at  a 
time  when  he  expected  that  the  minority  of  the  trustees  would  in- 
voke the  aid  of  the  Legislature  against  him,  and  his  idea  had  been 
remembered.  It  was  revived  at  the  time  of  the  newspaper  contro- 
versy, and  was  pressed  upon  the  attention  of  the  trustees  and  upon 
that  of  their  counsel.  But  the  lawyers  attached  little  weight  to  the 
suggestion,  although  they  introduced  it  and  argued  it  briefly.  Ma- 
son, Smith,  and  Webster  all  relied  for  success  on  the  ground  covered 
by  the  first  point  in  Mason's  brief.  This  is  called  by  Mr.  Shirley 
the  "  Parsons  view,"  from  the  fact  that  it  was  largely  drawn  from 
an  argument  made  by  Chief  Justice  Parsons  in  regard  to  visita- 
torial powers  at  Harvard  College.  Briefly  stated,  the  argument  was 
that  the  college  was  an  institution  founded  by  private  persons  for 
particular  uses ;  that  the  charter  was  given  to  perpetuate  such  uses ; 
that  misconduct  of  the  trustees  was  a  question  for  the  courts  and 
that  the  Legislature,  by  its  interference,  transcended  its  powers. 
To  these  general  principles,  strengthened  by  particular  clauses  in  the 
Constitution  of  New  Hampshire,  the  counsel  for  the  college  trusted 
for  victory.  The  theory  of  impairing  the  obligation  of  contracts  they 
introduced,  but  they  did  not  insist  on  it,  or  hope  for  much  from  it. 
On  this  point,  however,  and,  of  course,  on  this  alone,  the  case  went 
up  to  the  Supreme  Court.  In  December,  1817,  Mr.  Webster  wrote 
to  Mr.  Mason,  regretting  that  the  case  went  up  on  "  one  point  only." 
He  occupied  himself  at  this  time  in  devising  cases  which  should 
raise  what  he  considered  the  really  vital  points,  and  which,  coming 
within  the  jurisdiction  of  the  United  States,  could  be  taken  to  the 
Circuit  Court,  and  thence  to  the  Supreme  Court  at  Washington. 
These  cases,  in  accordance  with  his  suggestion,  were  begun,  but 
before  they  came  on  in  the  Circuit  Court,  Mr.  Webster  made  his 

seized  upon  to  support  the  argument  and  a  number  of  inferences  are 
drawn  which  have  seemed  to  the  writer,  from  a  general — not  a 
minute — reading  of  the  book  to  be  erroneously  drawn,  but  a  careful 
criticism  of  the  whole  work  will  not  be  attempted. 


96  OBLIGATION   OF  CONTRACTS  [640 

great  effort  at  Washington.  Three  quarters  of  his  legal  arguments 
were  there  devoted  to  the  point's  in  the  Circuit  Court  cases,  which 
were  not  in  any  way  before  the  Supreme  Court  in  the  College  vs. 
Woodward.  So  little,  indeed,  did  Mr.  Webster  think  of  the  great 
constitutional  question  which  has  made  the  case  famous,  that  he 
forced  the  other  points  in  where  he  admitted  that  they  had  no  proper 
standing,  and  argued  them  at  length.  They  were  touched  upon  by 
Marshall,  who,  however,  decided  wholly  upon  the  constitutional 
question,  and  they  were  all  thrown  aside  by  Judge  Washington,  who 
declared  them  irrelevant,  and  rested  his  decision  solely  and  properly 
on  the  constitutional  point.  Two  months  after  his  Washington  argu- 
ment, Mr.  Webster,  still  urging  forward  the  Circuit'  Court  cases, 
wrote  to  Mr.  Mason  that  all  the  questions  must  be  brought  properly 
before  the  Supreme  Court,  and  that,  on  the  "  general  principle  "  that 
the  State  Legislature  could  not  divest  rights,  strengthened  by  the 
constitutional  provisions  of  New  Hampshire,  he  was  sure  they  could 
defeat  their  adversaries.  Thus  this  doctrine  of  "  impairing  the  obli- 
gation of  contracts,"  which  produced  a  decision  in  its  effects  more 
far-reaching  and  of  more  general  interest  than  perhaps  any  other 
ever  made  in  this  country,  was  imported  into  the  case  at  the  sugges- 
tion of  laymen,  was  little  esteemed  by  counsel,  and  was  compara- 
tively neglected  in  every  argument.59 

The  popular  opinion  of  this  case  seems  to  be  that  Mr.  Webster, 
with  the  aid  of  Mr.  Mason  and  Judge  Smith,  developed  a  great  con- 
stitutional argument,  which  he  forced  upon  the  acceptance  of  the 
court  by  the  power  of  his  close  and  logical  reasoning,  and  thus 
established  an  interpretation  of  the  Constitution  of  vast  moment. 
The  truth  is,  that  the  suggestion  of  the  constitutional  point,  not  a 
very  remarkable  idea  in  itself,  originated,  as  has  been  said,  with  a 
layman,  was  regarded  by  Mr.  Webster  as  a  forlorn  hope,  and  was 
very  briefly  discussed  by  him  before  the  Supreme  Court.  He  knew 
of  course,  that  if  the  case  were  to  be  decided  against  Woodward,  it 
could  only  be  on  the  constitutional  point,  but  he  evidently  thought 
that  the  court  would  not  take  the  view  of  it  which  was  favorable 
to  the  college.60 

Mr.  Lodge  speaks  of  the  legal  argument  made  by  Webster 
as  strong,  effective  and  lucid,  but  dry,  cold  and  lawyerlike. 
He  continues : 

It  gives  no  conception  of  the  glowing  vehemence  of  the  delivery, 
or  of  those  omitted  portions  of  the  speech  which  dealt  with  matters 
outside  the  domain  of  law,  and  which  were  introduced  by  Mr.  Web- 
ster with  such  telling  and  important  results.  He  spoke  for  five 
hours,  but  in  the  printed  report  his  speech  occupies  only  three  pages 
more  than  that  of  Mr.  Mason  in  the  court  below.  Both  were  slow 
speakers,  and  thus  there  is  a  great  difference  in  time  to  be  accounted 
for,  even  after  making  every  allowance  for  the  peroration  which  we 
have  from  another  source,  and  for  the  wealth  of  legal  and  historical 
illustration  with  w.hich  Mr.  Webster  amplified  his  presentation  of 
the  question.  "  Something  was  left  out,"  Mr.  Webster  says,  and  that 
something  which  must  have  occupied  in  its  delivery  nearly  an  hour 

59  Lodge,  Life  of  Webster,  pp.  80-82. 
80  Ibid.,  pp.  07-98. 


641]  THE  DARTMOUTH  COLLEGE  CASE  97 

was  the  most  conspicuous  example  of  the  generalship  by  which  Mr. 
Webster  achieved  victory,  and  which  was  wholly  apart  from  his  law. 
This  art  of  management  had  already  been  displayed  in  the  treatment 
of  the  cases  made  up  for  the  Circuit  Courts,  and  in  the  elaborate 
and  irrelevant  legal  discussion  which  Mr.  Webster  introduced  be- 
fore the  Supreme  Court.  But  this  management  now  entered  on  a 
much  higher  stage,  where  it  was  destined  to  win  victory,  and  exhib- 
ited in  a  high  decree  tact  and  knowledge  of  men.  Mr.  Webster  was 
fully  aware  that  he  could  rely,  in  any  aspect  of  the  case,  upon  the 
sympathy  of  Marshall  and  Washington,  He  was  equally  certain  of 
the  unyielding  opposition  of  Duvall  and  Todd;  the  other  three 
judges,  Johnson,  Livingston,  and  Story,  were  known  to  be  adverse 
to  the  college,  but  were  possible  converts.  The  first  point  was  to 
increase  the  sympathy  of  the  Chief  Justice  to  an  eager  and  even 
passionate  support,  Mr.  Webster  knew  the  chord  to  strike,  and  he 
touched  it  with  a  master  hand.  This  was  the  "  something  left  out," 
of  which  we  know  the  general  drift,  and  we  can  easily  imagine  the 
effect.  In  the  midst  of  all  the  legal  and  constitutional  arguments, 
relevant  and  irrelevant,  even  in  the  pathetic  appeal  which  he  used  so 
well  in  behalf  of  his  Alma  Mater,  Mr.  Webster  bodly  and  yet  skil- 
fully introduced  the  political  view  of  the  case.  So  delicately  did  he 
do  it  that  an  attentive  listener  did  not  realize  that  he  was  straying 
from  the  field  of  "  mere  reason  "  into  that  of  political  passion.  Here 
no  man  could  equal  him  or  help  him,  for  here  his  eloquence  had  full 
scope,  and  on  this  he  relied  to  arouse  Marshall,  whom  he  thoroughly 
understood.  In  occasional  sentences  he  pictured  his  beloved  college 
under  the  wise  rule  of  Federalist's  and  of  the  Church.  He  depicted 
the  party  assault  that  was  made  upon  her.  He  showed  the  citadel 
of  learning  threatened  with  unholy  invasion  and  falling  helplessly 
into  the  hands  of  Jacobins  and  free-thinkers.  As  the  tide  of  his 
resistless  and  solemn  eloquence,  mingled  with  his  masterly  argu- 
ment, flowed  on,  we  can  imagine  how  the  great  Chief  Justice  roused 
like  an  old  war-horse  at  the  sound  of  the  trumpet.  The  words  of 
the  speaker  carried  him  back  to  the  early  years  of  the  century  when, 
in  the  full  flush  of  manhood,  at  the  head  of  his  court,  the  last  strong- 
hold of  Federalism,  the  last  bulwark  of  sound  government,  he  had 
faced  the  power  of  the  triumphant  Democrats.  Once  more  it  was 
Marshall  against  Jefferson, — the  judge  against  the  President.  Then 
he  had  preserved  the  ark  of  the  Constitution.  Then  he  had  seen  the 
angry  waves  of  popular  feeling  breaking  vainly  at  his  feet.  Now, 
in  his  old  age,  the  conflict  was  revived.  Jacobinism  was  raising  its 
sacreligious  hand  against  the  temples  of  learning,  against  the  friends 
of  order  and  good  government.  The  joy  of  battle  must  have  glowed 
once  more  in  the  old  man's  breast  as  he  grasped  anew  his  weapons 
and  prepared  with  all  the  force  of  his  indomitable  will  to  raise  yet 
another  constitutional  barrier  across  the  path  of  his  ancient  enemies. 
We  cannot  but  feel  that  Mr.  Webster's  lost  passages,  embodying 
this  political  appeal,  did  the  work,  and  that  the  result  was  settled 
when  the  political  passions  of  the  Chief  Justice  were  fairly  aroused. 
Marshall  would  probably  have  brought  about  the  decision  by  the 
sole  force  of  his  imperious  will.  But  Mr.  Webster  did  a  good  deal 
of  effective  work  after  the  arguments  were  all  finished,  and  no  ac- 
count of  the  case  would  be  complete,  without  a  glance  at  the  famous 
peroration  with  which  he  concluded  his  speech  and  in  which  he 


98  OBLIGATION   OF  CONTRACTS  [642 

boldly  flung  aside  all  vestige  of  legal  reasoning,  and  spoke  directly 
to  the  passions  and  emotions  of  his  hearerst.61 

Mr.  Lodge  describes  in  the  following  manner  the  efforts 
which  were  made  after  the  case  was  argued  to  create  public 
sentiment  in  favor  of  the  College : 

This  work  was  pushed  with  increased  eagerness  after  the  argument 
at  Washington,  and  the  object  now  was  to  create  about  the  three 
doubtful  judges  an  atmosphere  of  public  opinion  which  should  im- 
perceptibly bring  them  over  to  the  college.  Johnson,  Livingston, 
and  Story  were  all  men  who  would  have  started  at  the  barest  sus- 
picion of  outside  influence  even  in  the  most  legitimate  form  of  argu- 
ment, which  was  all  that  was  ever  thought  of  or  attempted.  This 
made  the  task  of  the  trustees  very  delicate  and  difficult  in  developing 
a  public  sentiment  which  should  sway  the  judges  without  their  being 
aware  of  it.  The  printed  arguments  of  Mason,  Smith,  and  Webster 
were  carefully  sent  to  certain  of  the  judges,  but  not  to  all.  All  docu- 
ments of  a  similar  character  found  their  way  to  the  same  quarters. 
The  leading  Federalists  were  aroused  everywhere,  so  that  the  judges 
might  be  made  to  feel  their  opinion.  With  Story,  as  a  New  England 
man,  a  Democrat  by  circumstances,  a  Federalist  by  nature,  there 
was  but  little  difficulty.  A  thorough  review  of  the  case,  joined  with 
Mr.  Webster's  argument,  caused  him  soon  to  change  his  first  im- 
pression. To  reach  Livingston  and  Johnson  was  not  so  easy,  for 
they  were  out  of  New  England,  and  it  was  necessary  to  go  a  long 
way  round  to  get  at  them.  The  great  legal  upholder  of  Federalism 
in  New  York  was  Chancellor  Kent.  His  first  impression,  like  that 
of  Story,  was  decidedly  against  the  college,  but  after  much  effort 
on  the  part  of  the  trustees  and  their  able  allies,  Kent  was  converted 
partly  through  his  reason,  partly  through  his  Federalism,  and  then 
his  powers  of  persuasion  and  his  great  influence  on  opinion  came  to 
bear  very  directly  on  Livingston,  more  remotely  on  Johnson.  The 
whole  business  was  managed  like  a  quiet,  decorous  political  cam- 
paign.62 

The  statement  thus  made  as  to  the  weakness  of  the  case 
of  the  College  in  the  opinion  of  its  counsel  seems  greatly 
exaggerated.  In  the  first  place,  the  argument  made  by 
computing  the  number  of  pages  devoted  by  counsel  in  their 
arguments  to  the  consideration  of  the  "contracts  clause," 
and  then  concluding  that  the  rest  of  the  arguments  of 
counsel  were  irrelevant  is  utterly  worthless.  As  we  have 
shown,  a  charter  could  only  be  established  as  a  contract 
under  the  "  contracts  clause "  by  showing  that  it  was  re- 
garded at  common  law  as  a  grant  of  a  private  property 
right.  The  three  headings  of  Mason's  argument,  which 

ai  Ibid.,  pp.  86-88. 
62  Ibid.,  pp.  92-93. 


643]  THE  DARTMOUTH  COLLEGE  CASE  99 

Webster  also  used,  were  mere  frames  on  which  to  set  the 
discussion  of  the  nature  of  the  corporate  franchise  as  a 
piece  of  property.  Had  Webster  omitted  the  first  two  head- 
ings and  retained  only  the  heading  that  the  acts  in  question 
impaired  the  obligation  of  a  contract,  only  about  six  pages, 
in  which  he  considers  in  detail  specific  clauses  of  the  New 
Hampshire  constitution,  of  his  whole  forty-nine  page  argu- 
ment would  have  become  irrelevant.  The  rest  would  not  only 
have  been  relevant,  it  would  have  been  absolutely  essential. 
The  inference  based  upon  the  page  calculation  is,  therefore, 
unfounded. 

Answering  another  of  the  points  made,  we  would  say  that 
we  have  not  discovered  that  Webster  ever  stated  that  he 
regarded  the  case  as  a  "  forlorn  hope."  That  seems  to  be 
an  inference  of  Mr.  Shirley.  The  expressions  found  in 
Webster's  correspondence  simply  amount  to  saying  that  he 
is  sorry  the  case  went  up  on  a  single  point  and  would  like  to 
bring  a  case  in  the  federal  courts  so  as  to  bring  the  whole 
case  before  the  Supreme  Court.68 

63  The  following  are  the  quotations  which  Mr.  Shirley  gives  from 
Webster's  correspondence. 

"  You  are  aware  that  in  the  college  cause  the  only  question  that 
can  be  argued  at  Washington  is  whether  the  recent  acts  of  the  Leg- 
islature of  New  Hampshire  do  not  violate  the  Constitution  of  the 
United  States.  This  point,  though  we  trust  a  strong  one,  is  not  per- 
haps stronger  than  that  derived  from  the  character  of  these  acts 
compared  with  the  Constitution  of  New  Hampshire.  It  has  occurred 
to  me  whether  it  would  not  be  well  to  bring  an  action  which  should 
present  both  and  all  our  points  to  the  Supreme  Court  .  .  ." 

"  It  is  our  misfortune  that  our  cause  goes  to  Washington  on  a 
single  point.  I  wish  we  had  it  in  such  shape  as  to  raise  all  the  other 
objections  as  well  as  the  repugnancy  of  these  acts  to  the  Constitu- 
tion of  the  United  States." 

"  I  am  sorry  our  college  cause  goes  to  Washington  on  one  point 
only.  What  do  you  think  of  an  action  in  some  court  of  the  United 
States  that  shall  raise  all  the  objections  to  the  act  in  question." 

"  I  am  glad  a  suit  is  to  be  brought  [in  the  federal  courts]." 

"  The  question  which  we  must  raise  in  one  of  these  actions,  is 
whether  by  the  general  principles  of  our  governments  the  State  Leg- 
islatures be  not  restrained  from  divesting  vested  right's.  This,  of 
course,  independently  of  the  constitutional  provision  respecting  con- 
tracts. On  this  question  I  have  great  confidence  in  a  decision  on  the 
right  side.  This  is  the  proposition  with  which  you  began  your  argu- 
ment at  Exeter  and  which  I  endeavored  to  state  from  your  minutes 
at  Washington."  Shirley,  pp.  5,  6. 


IOO  OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS  [644 

The  fact  that  the  Justices  of  the  Supreme  Court  were 
unable  to  reach  a  conclusion  the  day  after  the  case  was 
argued  is  sometimes  referred  to  as  warranting  the  inference 
that  a  number  of  the  Justices  were  at  that  time  unfavorable 
to  the  College,  and  had  to  be  brought  around  to  another 
way  of  thinking,  either  by  outside  influence  or  by  the  force 
of  the  Chief  Justice's  will,  but  the  inference  seems  rather 
extreme.  The  principal  source  of  information  as  to  the 
position  of  the  Justices  upon  the  case  at  that  time  is  found 
in  Webster's  letter  to  Smith,  of  March  18,  1818.  It  will  be 
noticed  that  the  statement  is  not  by  any  means  as  positive 
as  Mr.  Lodge's  statement  upon  the  same  subject.  Webster 
wrote : 

I  have  no  accurate  knowledge  of  the  manner  in  which  the  judges 
are  divided.  The  chief  and  Washington,  I  have  no  doubt,  are  with 
us.  Duval  and  Todd  are  perhaps  against  us ;  the  other  three  holding 
up.  I  cannot  much  doubt  but  that  Story  will  be  with  us  in  the  end, 
and  I  think  we  have  much  more  than  an  even  chance  with  one  of  the 
others.6* 

Again,  much  is  made  of  the  conversions  of  Story  and 
Kent,  who  had  originally  held  opinions  in  favor  of  the  new 
trustees.  We  do  not  marvel  at  Story's  conversion,  but  we 
are  surprised  at  the  fact  of  his  ever  having  held  another 
view,  considering  the  position  which  he  had  taken  four 
years  before,  in  the  case  of  Terrett  v.  Taylor,  in  regard  to 
the  sanctity  of  corporate  franchises. 

Kent  offers  a  very  reasonable  explanation  of  his  change 
of  opinion.  In  a  letter  to  Mr.  Marsh,  he  writes  that  he 
took  a  trip  through  New  Hampshire  to  recruit  his  spirits, 
stopped  off  at  Hanover  where  he  met  a  friend  who  intro- 
duced him  to  the  president  and  professors  of  the  univer- 
sity, but  did  not  meet  the  officers  of  the  college : 

Being  on  the  spot  and  witnessing  the  college  sessions  I  was 
anxious  to  know  something  of  the  controversy,  though  nothing  was 

64  Mr.  Shirley  gives  the  following  account  from  The  National  In- 
telligencer: "On  Friday  morning  [March  13,  1818]  the  chief  justice 
observed  that  the  judges  conferred  on  the  cause  between  the  Trus- 
tees of  Dartmouth  College  and  William  H.  Woodward.  Some  of 
the  judges  have  not  come  to  an  opinion  on  the  case.  Those  of  the 
judges  who  have  formed  opinions  do  not  agree.  The  cause  must 
therefore  be  continued  until  next  term."  Shirley,  p.  238. 


645]  THE  DARTMOUTH  COLLEGE  CASE  IOI 

said  on  the  subject  by  the  gentlemen  to  whom  I  was  introduced.  I 
had  often  casually  heard  the  subject  mentioned  but  knew  nothing  of 
its  merits.  After  some  search  I  was  enabled  to  purchase  the  opinion 
of  the  Supreme  Court  of  New  Hampshire  as  delivered  by  the  Chief 
Justice  and  read  it  the  next  day  on  my  return  to  Windsor.  That 
opinion  furnished  me  with  the  few  scanty  facts  I  possessed  in  regard 
to  the  great  constitutional  question  and  it  appeared  to  me  on  a  hasty 
perusal  of  it  that  the  legislature  was  competent  to  pass  the  laws  in 
question,  for  I  was  led  by  the  opinion  to  assume  the  fact  that  Dart- 
mouth College  was  a  public  establishment  for  purposes  of  a  general 
nature.  I  knew  nothing  nor  do  I  now  know  anything  material  in 
respect  to  the  policy  or  motives  of  the  laws  or  what  were  the  real 
inducements  to  pass  them. 

But  I  will  declare  to  you  with  equal  frankness  that  the  fuller 
statement  of  facts  in  Mr.  Webster's  argument  in  respect  to  the 
original  reasons  and  substance  of  the  charter  of  1769  and  the  sources 
of  the  gifts  gives  a  new  complexion  to  the  case  and  it  is  very  prob- 
able that  if  I  was  now  to  sit  down  and  seriously  study  the  case  with 
the  facts  at  large  before  me  that  I  should  be  led  to  a  different  con- 
clusion from  the  one  which  I  had  at  first  formed.  But  my  hasty 
impressions  one  way  or  the  other  are  not  worth  mentioning  for  I 
deem  them  of  no  value.  I  have  merely  stated  those  incidents  to 
show  how  very  acceptable  is  the  argument  you  sent  me. 

Mr.  Shirley  comments : 

As  has  already  been  suggested,  the  opinion  of  Judge  Richardson 
contained  a  statement  of  facts ;  and  the  pamphlet  produced  by  Kent 
gave  precisely  the  same  information  as  the  State  report.  Probably 
no  person  was  ever  misled  by  the  State  report — except  (?)  Chan- 
cellor Kent.  Strange  as  it  may  seem,  Daniel  Webster  and  Jeremiah 
Mason  never  discovered  it.65 

We  cannot  but  regard  such  a  comment  as  disingenuous. 
The  opinion  of  Richardson  did  give  the  facts  very  scantily 
and  made  no  mention  of  the  history  of  the  Indian  school, 
or  the  fact  that  Dr.  Wheelock  was  named  as  the  founder; 
and  it  is  easily  understandable  how  an  able  presentation  of 
one  side  of  a  case  will  draw  assent  from  one  not  already 
versed  in  the  particular  question  under  discussion,  when  a 
presentation  of  the  opposite  side  might  have  produced  an 
entirely  different  result. 

Mr.  Shirley  does  not  give  any  authorities  for  his  state- 
ment that  Webster  introduced  the  political  aspect  of  the 
case  into  his  argument,  but  the  probabilities  would  certainly 
be  that  he  did  so.  Mr.  Lodge's  very  interesting  picture  of 
the  nature  of  that  part  of  the  speech  and  its  effect  on  Mar- 

65  Shirley,  The  Dartmouth  College  Causes,  pp.  263-264. 


IO2  OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS  [646 

shall  is  probably  not  far  wrong.  It  seems,  nevertheless,  that 
this  feature  of  the  case  has  been  over-emphasized  because 
the  soundness  of  the  decision  from  the  legal  standpoint  has 
been  overlooked. 

Given  the  doctrine  of  Fletcher  v.  Peck,  the  questions  in 
the  College  case  were :  Was  a  charter  grant  a  grant  of  prop- 
erty? Were  charitable  or  educational  institutions,  public 
institutions?  These  questions  were  to  be  answered  by  ex- 
amining the  common  law  and  then  by  subjecting  it  to  such 
modifications  as  it  had  received  in  its  adaptation  to  the  needs 
of  this  country.  The  English  precedents  rather  clearly 
supported  the  court  upon  both  of  these  questions.  The 
court  might  have  said  that  the  English  doctrines  were  un- 
suited  to  this  country,  and  particularly  might  they  have  said 
that  these  educational  institutions  were  public  institutions. 
Here,  if  anywhere,  their  political  opinions  may  have  had 
some  play,  but  not,  perhaps,  as  much  as  has  often  been 
thought.66 

Our  view  of  Fletcher  v.  Peck  is  that  here,  also,  the  weight 
of  authority  upon  the  technical  questions  involved  supported 
the  opinion  of  the  majority.  But  any  judgment  upon  this 
case  must  be  subject  to  a  review  of  the  evidence  which  was 
available  to  the  court  as  to  whether  or  not  it  was  the  inten- 
tion of  those  who  framed  and  adopted  the  Constitution  that 
the  "contracts  clause"  should  extend  to  protect  the  con- 
tracts of  the  States,  which  is  a  matter  we  shall  shortly  con- 
sider. Of  the  two  cases,  Fletcher  v.  Peck,  took  far  the 
larger  step  toward  the  position  at  which  the  court  finally 
arrived.  It  established  the  principle  of  which  Dartmouth 
College  v.  Woodward  was  merely  the  application,  and  it  was 
with  this  conception  in  mind,  undoubtedly,  that  Marshall 
admitted  that  it  was  quite  possible  that  those  who  adopted 
the  Constitution  might  never  have  had  in  contemplation  the 
precise  case  of  grants  of  corporate  franchises. 

The  College  case  has,  however,  been  used  as  the  authority 

66  It  should  be  noted  that  Justice  Duval  dissented,  but  as  he  wrote 
no  opinion  his  reason  for  so  doing  cannot  be  known. 


647]  THE  DARTMOUTH   COLLEGE  CASE 

for  sustaining  all  other  franchise  grants  as  well  as  grants 
of  corporate  franchises,  because  these  secondary  franchises 
were  almost  always  found  in  the  charters  themselves,  and 
were  hence  considered  contracts  without  question.  The 
effect  of  the  ruling  in  the  College  case  is  now  and  has  for 
some  time  been  very  largely  nullified  by  the  reservation,  in 
the  grants  of  corporate  franchises,  of  the  right  to  alter, 
amend  or  repeal  them,  to  which  the  vast  majority  of  exist- 
ing charters  are,  without  doubt,  subject.  Its  effect  is  still 
noticeable  in  the  decisions  relating  to  secondary  franchises, 
such  as  the  franchises  in  city  streets  of  public  service  cor- 
porations, which  are  often  not  subject  to  this  reserved  right 
of  repeal. 

In  connection  with  the  College  case,  must  be  always  borne 
in  mind  the  modifying  doctrines  of  the  Charles  River  Bridge 
case,67  that  state  grants  are  to  be  construed  strictly  in  favor 
of  the  state ;  of  the  so-called  Granger  cases,68  that  businesses 
affected  with  a  public  interest  are  subject  to  legislative  regu- 
lation and  control ;  of  The  West  River  Bridge  Co.  v.  Dix69 
that  franchises  are  always  taken  subject  to  the  exercise  of 
the  power  of  eminent  domain  on  the  part  of  the  state ;  and 
of  Stone  v.  Mississippi,70  and  other  cases,  that  the  police 
power  cannot  be  alienated.  All  these  doctrines  were  un- 
doubtedly felt  to  be  necessary  limitations  upon  the  operation 
of  the  principles  of  the  College  case.  How  far  they  were 
actually  necessitated  would  depend  upon  how  general  the 
practice  had  become,  at  the  time  these  decisions  were  ren- 
dered, of  reserving  the  right  to  repeal  charters — a  question 
which  we  are  not  prepared  to  answer. 

The  effect  of  the  College  case  upon  the  body  politic  gen- 
erally is,  however,  a  question  upon  which  we  have  made  no 
special  investigation  and  which  is  indeed  most  difficult  of 
estimation.  It  may  be  said  that,  with  the  limitations  which 
have  been  affixed  to  the  doctrine,  and  with  the  reservation 

6Tii  Pet.  420  (1837). 

68  Munn  v.  Illinois,  94  U.  S.  113  (1876),  and  the  cases  following. 

e»  6  How.  507  (1848). 

TOioi  U.  S.  814  (1879). 


IO4  OBLIGATION  OF   CONTRACTS  [648 

of  the  right  of  repeal,  now  so  common,  there  is  not  much 
ground  for  complaining  of  its  being  burdensome,  although, 
as  said  before,  it  is  still  effective  in  the  case  of  many  second- 
ary franchises.  There  is  undoubtedly  much  truth  in  Mr. 
Cotten's  remark :  "  That  is  the  great  effect,  the  great  point 
of  the  case, — that  it  fixed  the  popular  as  well  as  the  legal 
mind  in  favor  of  the  stability  of  corporate  enterprise  and 
securities."71 

When  we  speak  of  the  limitations  which  have  been  affixed 
to  the  College  case  we  do  not  mean  to  infer  that  these  limi- 
tations are  necessarily  to  be  considered  as  deviations  from 
its  doctrine.  That  is  quite  a  different  question,  and  one 
which  we  shall  not  attempt  to  answer.  Logically  speaking, 
there  is  no  incompatibility  between  the  doctrines  of  The 
Charles  River  Bridge  case,  the  Granger  cases,  The  West 
River  Bridge  Co.  v.  Dix  and  Stone  v.  Mississippi,  and  the 

71  Marshall's  Decisions,  ed.  Gotten,  p.  349.  Sir  Henry  Maine  has 
said:  "I  have  seen  the  rule  which  denies  to  the  several  states  the 
power  to  make  any  laws  impairing  the  obligation  of  contracts  criti- 
cised as  if  it  were  a  mere  politico-economical  flourish;  but  in  point 
of  fact  there  is  no  more  important  provision  of  the  Constitution. 
Its  principle  was  much  extended  by  a  decision  of  the  Supreme  Court, 
which  ought  now  to  interest  a  large  number  of  Englishmen,  since 
it  is  the  basis  of  the  credit  of  many  of  the  great  American  railway 
incorporations.  But  it  is  this  prohibition  which  has  in  reality  secured 
full  play  to  the  economical  forces  by  which  the  achievement  of  culti- 
vating the  soil  of  the  North  American  continent  has  been  performed, 
it  is  the  bulwark  of  American  individualism  against  democratic 
impatience  and  socialistic  fantasy."  Maine,  Popular  Government 
(Essay  IV.),  p.  247.  Mr.  John  F.  Dillon  has  said:  "The  doctrine 
of  the  Dartmouth  College  case  as  applied  by  the  Supreme  Court  in 
it's  various  decisions,  is  not  only  sound,  but  has  been  one  of  the 
chief  causes  of  our  individual  and  national  prosperity."  John  Mar- 
shall, ed.  Dillon,  vol.  i,  p.  370.  Governor  Baldwin  says  in  his  Ameri- 
can Political  Institutions  at  p.  121 :  "  So  did  the  little  phrase  impair 
the  obligation  of  contracts, — like  the  genius  of  some  Arabian  tale 
at  the  touch  of  the  magic  wand  of  Chief  Justice  Marshall,  rise  and 
spread  into  the  form  of  that  invincible  champion  of  chartered  fran- 
chises by  which  the  whole  theory  of  American  corporations  was  to 
be  revolutionized  once  and  again.  And  so,  by  means  perhaps  less 
direct,  but  no  less  controlling,  has  a  new  meaning  been  read  into 
many  a  provision  of  statute  or  constitutions,  by  public  opinion  and 
the  lapse  of  time, — a  meaning  by  which  the  law,  it  may  be,  at  last 
ceases  to  protect  and  begins  to  oppress  society.  Has  not  this  been 
the  history  of  the  constitutional  guaranty  now  under  consideration?  " 
It  is,  however,  very  difficult  to  gauge  this  moral  effect  of  the  case. 


649]  THE  DARTMOUTH  COLLEGE  CASE  10$ 

doctrine  of  the  case  under  consideration.  The  question  is, 
Was  there  a  deviation  in  spirit  between  these  cases? 

It  may  be  noted  that  the  rule,  that  the  power  to  legislate 
as  to  the  forms  of  administering  justice  and  as  to  the  duties 
and  powers  of  the  courts  was  inalienable,  was  laid  down  in 
Bank  of  Columbia  v.  Okely,72  decided  at  the  same  term  of 
court  as  Dartmouth  College  v.  Woodward,  so  that  it  is  not 
apparent  that  the  later  rulings  as  to  the  inalienability  of  the 
power  of  eminent  domain  and  of  the  police  power  were 
opposed  to  the  spirit  of  the  College  case. 

As  both  the  Charles  River  Bridge  case  and  the  Granger 
cases  claim  to  be  merely  restatements  of  common  law  doc- 
trine, it  would  require  a  careful  examination  of  these  de- 
cisions to  see  how  far  they  were  supported  by  the  common 
law.  If  they  really  were  supported  by  common  law  prece- 
dents it  would  not  seem  correct  to  say  that  they  were  devia- 
tions from  the  spirit  of  the  College  case.  •  Story's  own  view 
of  the  Bridge  case  and  his  voucher  for  Marshall's73  affords 
strong  presumption,  however,  that  this  case  was  really  con- 
trary to  the  spirit  which  animated  the  justices  in  the  Col- 
lege case,  and  that  the  result  reached  was  largely  due  to  a 
changed  public  opinion  reflected  in  the  new  bench. 

The  case  of  Illinois  Central  v.  Illinois  R.  R.  Co.74  is  an 
interesting  one.  It  may  probably  be  said  to  be  a  departure 
from  the  spirit  of  the  College  case.  Here  it  was  held  that 
a  grant  to  a  railroad  company  of  an  area  of  more  than  a 
thousand  acres  of  the  submerged  land  in  the  harbor  of 
Chicago  was  merely  a  revocable  license.  The  extent  to 
which  the  decision  of  the  majority  was  based  upon  expedi- 
ency is  seen  from  their  admission  that  small  parcels  of  sub- 
merged land  such  as  are  necessary  for  the  construction  of 
docks  and  "which  when  occupied  do  not  substantially  im- 
pair the  public  interest  in  the  lands  and  waters  remaining  " 
might  be  granted.  So  submerged  shoals  and  flats  may  be 
ceded.  The  minority  come  rather  close  to  the  truth  when 

72  4  Wheat.  235,  245. 

73  i  Watson  on  the  Constitution,  p.  810. 
7*  146  U.  S.  487. 


IO6  OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS  [6$O 

they  say  that  the  ruling  of  the  majority  essentially  was  that 
too  big  a  grant  had  been  made. 

It  remains  to  present  a  few  other  suggestions  that  have 
been  made  concerning  the  case,  and  particularly  those  made 
by  Chief  Justice  Doe  in  the  article  already  referred  to. 

Chief  Justice  Doe  points  out  that  Marshall's  opinion  in 
the  College  case  is  very  largely  based  upon  the  fact  that 
property  had  been  given  to  the  corporation  upon  the  faith 
of  its  charter  which,  if  the  charter  was  subject  to  amend- 
ment or  repeal,  would  be  liable  to  forfeiture  to  the  state  or 
to  be  placed  under  the  immediate  control  of  the  state.  But 
as  it  has  since  been  held  that  the  property  of  corporations 
does  not  escheat  to  the  state  upon  the  repeal  of  the  charter, 
but  is  regarded  as  a  trust  fund  for  the  benefit  of  the  mem- 
bers of  the  corporation,  the  raison  d'etre  of  the  decision  in 
that  case,  he  maintains,  has  ceased  to  exist. 

This  argument  does  not,  of  course,  attack  the  validity  of 
the  decision  as  applicable  to  the  time  at  which  it  was  ren- 
dered, inasmuch  as  the  doctrine  that  the  corporate  property 
upon  dissolution  belongs  to  the  shareholders  was  at  that 
time  unheard  of.  Nor,  it  may  be  noticed,  could  the  argu- 
ment yet  be  used  in  the  case  of  religious  and  eleemosynary 
corporations  for,  as  to  these,  the  law  seems  still  to  be  that 
their  personal  property  is  forfeited  to  the  state  upon  the 
repeal  of  the  charter.75 

Again,  this  argument  does  not  affect  the  position  taken  by 
Justices  Story  and  Washington,  as  they  held  that  corporate 
franchises  were  property  per  se,  and  that  the  consideration 
for  the  grant  was  the  benefit  to  the  public  resulting  from 
the  exercise  of  these  powers.  Nor  is  it  clear  that  Marshall 
did  not  have  that  conception  also.  He  seems  to  express  it 
when  he  says:  "The  objects  for  which  a  corporation  is 
created  are  universally  such  as  the  government  wishes  to 
promote.  They  are  deemed  beneficial  to  the  country  and 
this  benefit  constitutes  the  consideration,  and  in  most  cases 
the  sole  consideration  of  the  grant."76 

75  Church  of  Latter  Day  Saints  v.  United  States,  136  U.  S.  I. 

76  12  Wheat.  518,  637. 


651]  THE  DARTMOUTH   COLLEGE  CASE 

Upon  the  abstract  question,  should  the  charters  of  busi- 
ness corporations  be  regarded  as  contracts,  the  argument  is 
of  some  value.  It  amounts  about  to  this:  that  incorpora- 
tors  do  not  give  the  state  any  real  consideration  for  these 
grants  of  corporate  franchises  and  therefore  they  should 
not  be  considered  to  be  irrepealable.  Were  the  question  to 
be  decided  to-day,  the  argument  might  well  prevail.77 

77  Morawetz,  in  his  work  on  private  corporations,  states  that  it  is 
hard  to  find  any  contract  between  the  state  and  its  corporations, 
although  he  apparently  thinks  that  one  exists  in  the  case  of  a  special 
grant  of  corporate  privileges.  In  the  case  of  corporations  formed 
under  the  provisions  of  a  general  law,  he  finds  that,  although  there 
is  no  contract  between  the  state  and  the  incorporators,  there  is  a 
contract  between  the  corporators  themselves  which,  under  the  "  con- 
tract clause,"  the  state  is  forbidden  to  impair.  Thus  he  says  that 
although  the  charter  creates  no  contract  between  the  state  and  the 
incorporators,  nevertheless  the  state  cannot  amend  the  charter  so 
as  to  alter  the  purposes  of  the  corporation,  as  that  would  impair  the 
obligation  of  the  contract  entered  into  among  the  incorporators.  It 
is  rather  doubtful  if  this  is  a  logically  correct  position.  Mr.  Mora- 
wetz goes  so  far  as  to  hold  that  the  state  caiinot  repeal  a  charter, 
because  to  do  so  would  impair  the  obligation,  not  of  the  contract 
between  the  corporators  themselves,  a  position  which,  it  seems  to  us, 
is  unsound.  See  Morawetz,  Private  Corporations,  Sees.  1047.  1048, 
1054.  In  Taylor  on  Corporations  is  found  this  criticism  of  the  case : 

"  Sec.  450 :  One  may  well  raise  the  question  whether  this  implied 
contract  not  to  alter  the  constitution  of  a  corporation  would  be  held 
to  exist,  did  the  matter  arise  as  res  nova  in  regard  to  a  general 
enabling  statute.  If  the  right  to  repeal  were  not  reserved,  pre- 
sumably, under  the  authority  of  past  decisions,  courts  would  hold 
that  the  statute  could  not  be  repealed  or  changed  so  as  to  affect  the 
right  of  existing  corporations  to  carry  on  their  business  as  under 
the  statute.  But  would  courts  so  hold  in  regard  to  a  statute  sanc- 
tioning limited  partnerships?  Is  there  any  implied  contract  between 
the  state  and  a  limited  partnership  any  more  than  between  the  state 
and  an  ordinary  firm?  No  citizen  by  acting  under  a  statute,  any 
more  t'han  by  acting  under  a  rule  of  common  law,  acquires  a  right 
that  the  statute  shall  remain  unrepealed  so  that  he  may  always*  act 
under  and  be  protected  by  its  terms.  And  why  should  there  be  held 
to  exist  an  implied  contract  between  the  state  and  an  ordinary  busi- 
ness corporation  any  more  than  between  the  state  and  a  limited 
partnership?  Still  who  is  today  rash  enough  to  hint  that  the  de- 
cision in  the  Dartmouth  College  Case  was  based  on  the  false  analogy 
between  a  grant  of  a  franchise  (i.  e.  the  passage  of  a  special  law), 
and  the  grant  of  property?  As  Justice  Davis  said  in  the  Binghamp- 
ton  Bridge :  Court's  are  today  estopped  from  questioning  the  doc- 
trine of  the  Dartmouth  College  Case. 

"  Sec.  451 :  That  the  constitution  of  a  corporation  is  law  is  more 
apparent  in  respect  of  corporations  formed  under  general  enabling 
statutes,  while  the  characteristics  of  a  contract  appear  more  promi- 
nently where  a  special  charater  is  granted  by  the  state  to  the  cor- 


108  OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS  [652 

Chief  Justice  Doe  makes  the  further  criticism  upon  the 
College  case  that  even  had  the  charter  been  granted  by  the 
legislature  of  New  Hampshire  instead  of  by  the  King  of 
England,  it  could  not  have  constituted  an  irrepealable  con- 
tract for,  inasmuch  as  the  legislature's  power  of  law-making 
had  been  merely  delegated  by  the  State,  that  body  could 
not  contract  away  this  power.  But  if  it  be  conceded  that 
the  States  can  contract,  it  would  seem  to  be  very  narrow 
and  technical  reasoning  to  contend  that  the  power  to  con- 
tract is  not  granted  to  the  legislature  under  the  ordinary 
grant  of  legislative  power  found  in  the  State  constitutions. 

Again,  Chief  Justice  Doe  suggests  that,  under  the  doc- 
trine of  the  strict  construction  of  state  contracts,  which  has 
been  elaborated  since  the  College  case,  upon  the  authority 
of  the  Charles  River  Bridge  case,  it  can  not  be  said  that  a 
grant  of  corporate  franchises  contains  a  contract  not  to  re- 
peal them,  when  the  only  way  in  which  such  a  contract  can 
be  found  is  by  implying  one. 

It  may  be  that  such  a  conclusion  is  entirely  compatible 
with  a  logical  application  of  the  rule  of  strict  construction. 
But  the  rule  of  strict  construction  is  not  always  applied  with 
logical  precision.  The  court  is  inclined  to  protect  those 
who  have  expended  large  sums  of  money  on  the  faith  of 
legislative  grants,  and  has  adhered  to  the  principle  that 
when  the  legislature  grants  franchises  upon  the  faith  of 
which  large  sums  of  money  are  spent,  although  such  fran- 
chises are  not  expressly  stated  to  be  irrevocable,  and  though 
no  time  is  fixed  for  the  duration  of  such  franchises,  never- 

porators.  The  differences  between  an  enabling  statute  and  a  charter 
are,  however,  mainly  differences  in  form.  A  charter  as  well  as  an 
enabling  statute  prescribes  rules  for  conduct;  the  difference  being 
that  these  rules  in  the  case  of  a  charter  have  a  more  limited  appli- 
cation. And  as  an  enabling  statute,  as  well  as  a  charter,  proffers 
terms  and  facilities  of  action  which  are  accepted  by  the  corporators 
by  filing  their  articles  of  association,  only  in  the  case  of  an  enabling 
statute  the  terms  are  offered  to  the  citizens  of  the  state  at  large,  any 
sufficient  number  of  whom  may  accept  them  and  incorporate  them- 
selves by  complying  with  them."  Taylor,  Corporations,  pp.  432-437. 
It  is  difficult  to  perceive  whether  Mr.  Taylor's  idea  is  that  no  cor- 
porate charters  are  contracts  or  only  that  corporations  incorporated 
under  the  general  law  have  no  contract  right's  as  against  the  state." 


653]  THE  DARTMOUTH  COLLEGE  CASE  IO9 

thless  there  is  a  condition  implied  in  them  that  the  legisla- 
ture will  not  revoke  its  grant.  If  Justice  Doe's  position 
were  correct,  no  public  utility  franchises  would  be  contracts 
unless  a  specific  period  of  existence  was  named  in  them,  and 
possibly  not  then,  if  they  are  not  expressly  made  irrevocable. 
But  the  Supreme  Court  has  recently  held  that  grants  of 
franchises  in  the  streets  of  cities  to  public  utility  companies, 
under  which  large  sums  of  money  are  to  be  spent,  are, 
although  not  expressly  made  irrevocable,  and  although  their 
duration  is  not  specified,  of  perpetual  duration.78 

It  has  already  been  remarked,  in  the  part  of  this  chapter 
in  which  the  general  question  of  the  power  of  the  States  to 
contract  was  considered,  that  there  are  no  very  clear  logical 
lines  to  be  drawn  between  contracts  which  the  States  may 
make  and  those  which  they  may  not  make.  The  question 
may  almost  be  said  to  be  one  of  policy.  Thus  much  room 
is  left  for  difference  of  opinion  upon  this,  matter.  It  would 
seem  that  a  line  may  properly  be  drawn  somewhere  between 
contracts  concerning  property,  on  the  one  side,  and  con- 
tracts concerning  essential  governmental  powers,  on  the 
other.  Practically  every  one  will  agree  that  it  now  seems 
rather  incongruous  to  consider  the  taxing  power  as  a  sub- 
ject of  contract.  It  would  seem  much  more  reasonable  to 
place  it  along  with  the  power  of  eminent  domain,  the  police 
power,  and  the  power  of  administering  justice,  as  not  capa- 
ble of  being  made  the  subject  of  contract.  Public  service 
franchises  have  uniformly  been  regarded  as  in  the  nature 
of  property,  and  hence  as  the  subject  of  contract.  Con- 
tracts exempting  public  service  corporations  from  rate  regu- 
lation are  close  to  the  line.  Another  close  case  is  that  of 
Illinois  Central  R.  Co.  v.  Illinois,79  where  it  was  held  that 
the  State  could  not  make  irrevocable  grant  of  land  covered 
by  navigable  waters,  if  it  will  substantially  impair  the  public 
interest  in  the  lands  and  waters  remaining. 

T8Owensboro  v.  Cumberland  Telephone  Co.,  230  U.  S.  58;  Old 
Colony  Trust  Co.  v.  Omaha,  230  U.  S.  100 ;  Boise  Water  Co.  v.  Boise 
City,  230  U.  S.  84. 

"U.  8.387. 


HO  OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS  [654 

It  remains  to  review  the  proceedings  of  the  Constitutional 
Convention  of  1787,  of  the  State  conventions,  and  the  other 
historical  data  concerning  the  adoption  of  the  "  contracts 
clause."  Justice  Miller,  in  his  lectures  on  the  Constitution 
has  said: 

It  has  seemed  probable  to  many  judges  and  lawyers  who  have  con- 
sidered this  clause  of  the  Constitution  that  it  was  not  designed  by 
the  framers  of  that  instrument  to  dp  anything  more  than  protect 
private  contract's,  those  between  individuals  and  those  between  indi- 
viduals and  private  corporations,  that  is,  not  municipal  corporations, 
but  those  organized  for  purposes  of  profit;  and  if  it  were  now  an 
original  question,  it  is  by  no  means  certain  but  that  this  would  be 
held  to  be  the  sound  view  of  it.  But  those  eminent  men  who  at  an 
early  day  had  the  duty  of  defining  the  meaning  of  this  provision 
thought  otherwise.80 

80  Miller  on  the  Constitution,  p.  555. 


CHAPTER  V 

THE  "  OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS  CLAUSE  "  AS  VIEWED  BY 
THE  FRAMERS  OF  THE  CONSTITUTION 

Heretofore  we  have  been  engaged  in  a  more  or  less  tech- 
nical examination  of  the  "contracts  clause"  and  the  de- 
cisions construing  it.  We  have  been  able  to  proceed  thus 
far  without  considering  the  historical  surroundings  of  the 
clause,  because  the  decisions  themselves  were  based  on  tech- 
nical, rather  than  historical  considerations.  It  remains  for 
us,  however,  to  review  the  proceedings  in  the  Constitutional 
Convention  and  the  other  available  data,  to  check  up,  as  it 
were,  the  results  already  reached.  The  purpose  will  be 
twofold:  to  ascertain  whether  the  information  at  the  dis- 
posal of  the  court  when  the  important  decisions  were  made 
was  such  as  should  have  assured  a  different  result  from  that 
actually  reached ;  secondly,  to  ascertain,  as  a  matter  of  in- 
terest, what  further  opinions,  undisclosed  at  the  time  of  the 
rendering  of  the  decisions  before  mentioned,  were  held  by 
the  "  Fathers  "  as  to  this  clause. 

In  truth  the  court  had  little  in  the  way  of  historical  infor- 
mation to  assist  it  in  laying  out  the  field  to  be  covered  by 
the  "contracts  clause."  The  intentions  of  the  Convention 
itself  could  not  be  ascertained,  for  the  journal  and  debates 
were  not  published  until  after  the  important  cases  on  this 
subject  had  been  decided.  The  members  of  the  Conven- 
tion, moreover,  had  been  pledged  to  secrecy.1  Was  there 
then  a  clear  conception  of  the  meaning  of  the  clause  pre- 
vailing generally  throughout  the  land,  at  the  time  the  Con- 
stitution was  adopted? 

1 1  Farrand,  The  records  of  the  Federal  Convention,  pp.  xi,  xiv. 
The  journal  was  published  in  1819.  Various  minutes  were  later 
published  from  time  to  time,  and  finally  Madison's  Minutes  of  the 
debates  were  published  in  1840. 

in 


112  OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS  [6$6 

Turning,  first,  to  the  Federalist,  the  primary  source  of 
information  on  questions  such  as  these  and  which,  doubt- 
less, acted  as  the  most  potent  agency  for  moulding  public 
opinion  on  matters  of  this  kind,  we  find  that  the  only  treat- 
ment of  the  clause  is  in  Number  44,  at  the  hands  of  Madi- 
son. He  there  says : 

Bills  of  attainder,  ex  post  facto  laws,  and  laws  impairing  the  obli- 
gation of  contracts,  are  contrary  to  the  first  principles  of  the  social 
compact  and  to  every  principle  of  sound  legislation.  The  two  former 
are  expressly  prohibited  by  the  declarations  prefixed  to  some  of  the 
State  constitutions,  and  all  of  them  are  prohibited  by  the  spirit  and 
scope  of  these  fundamental  charters.  Our  own  experience  has  taught 
us,  nevertheless,  that  additional  fences  against  these  dangers  ought 
not  to  be  omitted.  Very  properly,  therefore,  have  the  convention 
added  this  constitutional  bulwark  in  favor  of  personal  security  and 
private  rights,  and  I  am  much  deceived  if  they  have  not,  in  so  doing, 
as  faithfully  consulted  the  genuine  sentiments  as  the  undoubted 
interests  of  their  constituent's.  The  sober  people  of  America  are 
weary  of  the  fluctuating  policy  which  has  directed  the  public  coun- 
cils. They  have  seen  with  regret  and  indignation  that  sudden  changes 
and  legislative  interferences,  in  cases  affecting  personal  rights,  be- 
come jobs  in  the  hands  of  enterprising  and  influential  speculators, 
and  snares  to  the  more  industrious  and  less  informed  part  of  the 
community.  They  have  seen  too,  that  one  legislative  interference  is 
but  the  first  link  of  a  long  chain  of  repetitions,  every  subsequent 
interference  being  naturally  produced  by  the  effects  of  the  preceding. 
They  very  rightly  infer,  therefore,  that  some  thorough  reform  is 
wanting,  which  will  banish  speculations  on  public  measures,  inspire 
a  general  prudence  and  industry,  and  give  a  regular  course  to  the 
business  of  society."2 

In  the  discussion  of  the  first  clause  of  section  10  in  the 
Virginia  convention  Patrick  Henry  feared  that  it  might  re- 
quire the  States  to  pay  the  continental  paper  money  in  full. 
Speaking  of  ex  post  facto  laws  and  laws  impairing  the  obli- 
gation of  contracts,  he  said :  "  The  expression  includes  pub- 
lic contracts,  as  well  as  private  contracts  between  indivi- 
duals. Notwithstanding  the  sagacity  of  the  gentleman,  he 
cannot  prove  its  exclusive  relation  to  private  contracts."3 
The  answer  given  to  this  contention  was  that  Congress  and 
not  the  States  had  contracted  to  pay  this  debt.  Governor 
Randolph  called  Henry's  attention  to  the  fact  that  Congress 
was  only  forbidden  to  pass  ex  post  facto  laws  which  re- 

2  Federalist,  ed.  Ford,  p.  297. 
•  2  Elliott's  Debates,  474. 


657]       AS  VIEWED  BY  FRAMERS  OF  THE  CONSTITUTION         113 

f erred  only  to  criminal  matters.    He  also  said: 

I  am  still  a  warm  friend  of  the  prohibition,  because  it  must  be 
promotive  of  virtue  and  justice,  and  preventive  of  injustice  and 
fraud.  If  we  take  a  review  of  the  calamities  which  have  befallen 
our  reputation  as  a  people,  we  shall  find  they  have  been  produced  by 
frequent  interferences  of  the  state  legislatures  with  private  con- 
tracts. If  you  will  inspect  the  great  cornerstone  of  republicanism, 
you  will  find  it  to  be  justice  and  honor.4 

It  will  be  noticed  that  Randolph  nowhere  denies  Henry's 
contention  that  the  "contracts  clause"  refers  to  the  con- 
tracts of  the  States  as  well  as  to  those  between  individuals. 
In  the  debate  in  the  North  Carolina  convention  the  ques- 
tion was  raised,  whether  the  clause  had  reference  to  the 
contracts  of  the  States  as  well  as  to  contracts  made  between 
individuals.  W.  R.  Davie,  a  member  of  the  Constitutional 
Convention,  answered  it  in  the  negative,  saying: 

Mr.  Chairman,  I  believe  neither  the  loth  section,  cited  by  the  gen- 
tleman, nor  any  other  part  of  the  Constitution,  has  vested  the  gen- 
eral government  with  power  to  interfere  with  the  public  securities  of 
any  state.  I  will  venture  to  say  that  the  last  thing  which  the  general 
government  will  attempt  to  do  will  be  this.  They  have  nothing  to 
dp  with  it.  The  clause  refers  merely  to  contracts  between  indi- 
viduals.5 

There  does  not  appear  to  have  been  any  debate  over  the 
clause  in  a  single  other  State  convention,  and  the  only  other 
mention  of  it  is  to  be  found  in  Sherman's  and  Ellsworth's 
letter  to  the  governor  of  Connecticut,  and  in  Luther  Mar- 
tin's "  Genuine  Information  "  to  the  Maryland  Legislature. 
Sherman  and  Ellsworth  say: 

The  restraint  on  the  legislatures  of  the  several  states  respecting 
emitting  bills  of  credit,  making  anything  but  money  a  tender  in  pay- 
ment of  debts,  or  impairing  the  obligation  of  contracts  by  ex  post 
facto  laws,  was  thought  necessary  as  a  security  to  commerce,  in 
which  the  interests  of  foreigners,  as  well  as  of  the  citizens  of  dif- 
ferent states  may  be  affected.6 

Martin  said : 

The  same  section  also  puts  it  out  of  the  power  of  the  States  to 
make  any  thing  but  gold  or  silver  coin  a  tender  in  payment  of  debts, 

4  Ibid.,  478. 

8  3  Farrand,  Records  of  the  Federal  Convention,  p.  349. 
6  Ibid.,  vol.  iii,  p.  100. 
8 


114  OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS  [658 

or  to  pass  any  law  impairing  the  obligations  of  contracts.  I  con- 
sidered, Sir,  that  there  might  be  times  of  such  great  puWic  calamities 
and  distress,  and  of  such  extreme  scarcity  of  species,  as  should 
render  it  the  duty  of  a  government,  for  the  preservation  of  even 
the  most  valuable  part  of  it's  citizens,  in  some  measure  to  interfere 
in  their  favor  by  passing  laws  totally  or  partially  stopping  the  courts 
of  justice,  or  authorizing  the  debtor  to  pay  by  instalments  or  by 
delivering  up  his  property  to  his  creditors  at'  a  reasonable  and  honest 
valuation.  The  times  have  been  such  as  to  render  regulations  of 
this  kind  necessary  in  most  or  all  of  the  States,  to  prevent  the 
wealthy  creditor  and  the  moneyed  man  from  totally  destroying  the 
poor  though  even  industrious  debtor.  Such  times  may  again  arrive. 
I  therefore  voted  against  depriving  the  States  of  this  power,  a  power 
which  I  am  decided  they  ought  to  possess,  but  which,  I  admit',  ought 
only  to  be  exercised  on  very  important  and  urgent  occasions.  I 
apprehend,  Sir,  the  principal  cause  of  complaint  among  the  people 
at  large  is  the  public  and  private  debt  with  which  they  are  oppressed, 
and  which  in  the  present  scarcity  of  cash,  threatens  them  with  de- 
struction, unless  they  can  obtain  so  much  indulgence  in  point  of 
time,  that  by  industry  and  frugality  they  may  extricate  themselves.7 

A  provision  in  the  Northwest  Ordinance,  passed  by  Con- 
gress in  1787  before  the  work  of  the  convention  was  fin- 
ished, may  also  be  noticed  on  account  of  the  similarity  of 
the  language  used  and,  as  well,  on  account  of  the  differ- 
ences. The  clause  reads  as  follows : 

And  in  the  just  preservation  of  rights  and  property,  it  is  under- 
stood and  declared,  that  no  law  ought  ever  to  be  made  or  have  force 
in  the  said  territory  that  shall  in  any  manner  whatever  interfere 
with  or  affect  private  contracts  or  engagement's  bona  fide  and  with- 
out fraud  previously  formed. 

This  was  all  the  documentary  evidence  that  the  court 
could  have  had  in  making  its  important  decisions  as  to  the 
meaning  to  be  attributed  to  the  "contracts  clause."  Of 
course  it  is  true  that  the  State  laws  passed  during  the  exist- 
ence of  the  Confederation  which  had  impaired  the  obliga- 
tion of  private  contracts  by  issuing  depreciated  paper  cur- 
rency and  making  it  legal  tender,  allowing  debts  to  be 
satisfied  in  property  or  paid  in  installments,  and  hindering 
creditors  in  their  efforts  to  obtain  redress,8  were  necessarily 
matters  of  common  knowledge.  Considering  then  the  par- 
ticular evils  which  seem  to  have  inspired  the  adoption  of  the 

1 1bid.,  vol.  iii,  p.  214. 

8  See  Madison's  introduction  to  the  debates,  3  Farrand,  Records  of 
the  Federal  Convention,  p.  548. 


659]       AS  VIEWED  BY  FRAMERS  OF  THE  CONSTITUTION       11$ 

clause,  the  statement  of  Davie  in  the  North  Carolina  con- 
vention and  the  general  trend  of  Martin's  argument  as  it 
was  found  in  his  Genuine  Information  (although  there  is 
no  means  of  knowing  whether  the  latter  two  sources  of 
information  were  actually  presented  to  the  court),  an  infer- 
ence might  have  been  drawn  that  only  private  contracts 
were  intended  to  be  protected. 

Against  this  may  be  placed  several  important  considera- 
tions. The  first  and  most  important  of  all — one  that  we 
have  already  had  occasion  to  call  attention  to  and  which,  we 
think,  has  been  too  often  overlooked  in  considering  the 
course  of  the  early  decisions  upon  this  clause  of  the  Consti- 
tution— is  that  the  most  eminent  jurists  of  the  day,  both  at 
the  time  of  the  convention  and  for  some  years  afterwards, 
were  firm  adherents  to  the  doctrine  of  natural  law.  They 
were  familiar  with  the  theory  of  the  natural  obligation  of 
contracts;  they  were  familiar  with  the  theory  of  the  social 
compact;  and  the  idea  of  a  state's  being  bound  by  its  con- 
tract must  have  been  a  perfectly  natural  one  to  them. 

Jurists  imbued  with  the  theories  of  Austin,  to  whom  the 
idea  of  the  state's  being  obligated  by  a  contract  made  with 
one  of  its  citizens  has  always  been  an  incongruous  one,  are 
apt  to  feel  that  the  court  was  legislating  in  a  most  active 
way  when  it  declared  that  the  contracts  of  the  States  were 
included  within  the  operation  of  the  "contracts  clause." 
They  say  that,  what  with  the  jealousy  exhibited  by  the 
States  on  all  occasions  and  with  the  very  narrow  margin  by 
which  the  Constitution  was  actually  carried  through,  it  is 
inconceivable  that  it  would  have  been  adopted  had  the 
meaning  of  the  "contracts  clause,"  as  it  later  developed, 
been  fully  explained. 

We  have  already  suggested,  as  a  partial  answer,  that  the 
theory  of  natural  law,  which  recognized  the  contracts  of 
states  equally  with  those  of  individuals,  was  generally  ac- 
cepted at  that  time.  Several  proof  s  of  this  may  be  adduced. 
James  Wilson— ^member  of  the  Constitutional  Convention, 


Il6  OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS  [660 

the  reputed  author  of  the  "contracts  clause,"9  one  of  the 
most  influential  men  of  his  day,  "  reputed  among  the  fore- 
most in  legal  and  political  knowledge,"10  and  later  a  justice 
of  the  Supreme  Court  of  the  United  States — published  in 
1792  a  number  of  lectures  which  he  had  delivered  to  a  body 
of  students.  The  following  extracts  from  the  lectures  will 
illustrate  the  views  which  he  held.  "Sir  William  Black- 
stone,"  says  Wilson,  "  tells  us  that  the  original  of  the  obli- 
gation which  a  compact  carries  with  it,  is  different  from 
that  of  a  law.  The  original  of  the  obligation  of  a  compact 
we  know  to  be  consent :  the  original  of  the  obligation  of  an 
act  of  parliament  we  have  traced  minutely  to  the  very  same 
source."  Again,  he  says,  page  190:  "Consent  is  the  sole 
principle  on  which  any  claim,  in  consequence  of  human 
authority,  can  be  made  upon  one  man  by  another.  Exclu- 
sively of  the  duties  required  by  the  law  of  nature,  I  can 
conceive  of  no  claim  that  one  man  can  make  upon  another 
but  in  consequence  of  his  own  consent."  Naturally,  to  such 
a  one,  the  spectacle  of  a  state's  being  bound  by  a  contract 
was  perfectly  congenial ;  and  so  we  find :  "  It  [the  state]  is 
an  artificial  person — it  has  its  obligations  and  it  has  its 
rights.  It  may  acquire  property  distinct  from  that  of  its 
members,  it  may  incur  debts,  to  be  discharged  out  of  the 
public  stock,  not  out  of  the  private  fortunes  of  individuals : 
it  may  be  bound  by  contracts  and  for  damages  arising  quasi 
ex  contractu"11  It  may  also  be  mentioned  that,  in  1785,  he 
had  published  an  argument  in  opposition  to  a  bill  which  had 
been  introduced  in  the  Pennsylvania  Legislature  for  the 
purpose  of  repealing  the  charter  granted  by  the  State  of 
Pennsylvania  to  the  Bank  of  North  America,  in  which  he 
argued  that  the  charter  was  a  contract  and  that  the  legisla- 
ture, therefore,  had  no  power  to  repeal  it.12 

9  See  argument  in  Sturges  v.  Crown  in  shield,  4  Wheat.  122. 

10  3  Far  rand,  Records  of  the  Federal  Convention,  p.  91. 

11 1  Wilson's  Works,  ed.  Andrews,  p.  183.  It  should  be  stated  that 
he  had  made  the  argument  as  counsel  for  the  bank  before  the  leg- 
islature. 

12  2  Wilson's  Works,  ed.  Andrews,  p.  565. 


66 1]       AS  VIEWED  BY  FRAMERS  OF  THE  CONSTITUTION 

The  doctrine  which  he  then  put  forward  is  summed  up  in 
this  form:  "For  these  reasons,  whenever  the  objects  and 
makers  of  an  instrument,  passed  under  the  form  of  a  law, 
are  not  the  same,  it  is  ^o  be  considered  as  a  compact  and 
interpreted  according  t.6  the  rules  and  maxims  by  which 
compacts  are  governed."13 

A  brief  statement  from  Merriam's  American  Political 
Theories  will  show  the  current  political  theory  of  revolu- 
tionary and  post-revolutionary  times.  That  writer  says:14 

By  way  of  summary,  it  may  be  said  that  the  leading  doctrines  of 
the  revolutionary  penod  were  those  of  what  is  known  as  the  Natur- 
recht  school  of  political  theory.  They  included  the  idea  of  an  origi- 
nal state  of  nature,  in  which  all  men  are  born  politically  free  and 
equal,  the  contractual  origin  of  government,  the  sovereignty  of  the 
people  and  the  right  of  revolution  against  a  government  regarded 
as  oppressive.  ...  It  will  be  observed  that  the  spirit  of  this  rea- 
soning was  decidedly  individualistic.  The  starting  point  was  the 
independent  and  sovereign  individual  endowed  with  a  full  set  of 
natural  rigl  ts.  He  consents  to'  give  up  a  part  of  these  natural  rights 
to  form  a  government  by  means  of  a  compact.- 

Not  only  was  this  natural  law  and  social  compact  theory 
an  accepted  philosophical  doctrine;  it  is  often  found  stated 
in  the  opinions  of  the  courts  as  well.  Thus,  in  Calder  v. 
Bull,15  decided  in  1796,  we  find  a  polished  and  elaborate 
statement  of  it  by  Justice  Chase.  Then,  in  the  early  case 
of  Vanhorne's  Lessee  v.  Dorrance,16  decided  in  1795,  we  find 
Justice  Patterson  of  the  Supreme  Court  contemplating  with 
equanimity  the  possibility,  not  only  of  an  act  of  the  legisla- 
ture's constituting  a  contract,  but  of  its  constituting  a  con- 
tract within  the  meaning  of  the  "  contracts  clause."  In  an- 
swer to  an  argument  of  counsel  to  the  effect  that  the  act  in 
question  impaired  the  obligation  of  a  contract,  he  merely 
says :  "  But  if  the  confirming  act  be  a  contract  between  the 
Legislature  of  Pennsylvania  and  the  Connecticut  settlers,  it 
must  be  governed  by  the  rules  and  regulations  which  per- 
vade all  cases  of  contracts  and  if  so,  it  is  clearly  void." 

13  I  Wilson's  Works,  ed.  Andrews,  p.  565. 

14  American  Political  Theories,  pp.  94-95. 

15  3  Dall.  386. 

16  2  Dall.  304. 


118  OBLIGATION  OF  ^CONTRACTS  [662 

The  proceedings  in  the  Virginia  convention  were  favor- 
able. ^ 

The  language  of  the  Federalist*  which  we  have  already 
quoted,  was  very  broad  and  generjil.  It  is  not  specific,  of 
course,  but  the  very  fact  was  one  vto  which  the  court  did, 
and  we  think  rightly,  attach  considerable  weight.  Justice 
Johnson,  who  dissented  in  Fletcher  v.  Peck,  was  ready  to 
admit  that  the  clause  applied  to  the  contracts  of  the  States. 
Speaking  of  this  clause,  he  said:  "Tfcere  is  reason  to  be- 
lieve, from  the  letters  of  Publius,  which  are  well  entitled 
to  the  highest  respect,  that  the  object  of  the  convention  was 
to  afford  a  general  protection  to  individual  rights  against 
the  acts  of  the  state  legislature.  Whether  (he  words  'acts 
impairing  the  obligation  of  contracts'  can  be  construed  to 
have  the  same  force  as  must  have  been  given  to  the  words 
'obligation  and  effect  of  contracts'  is  the  difficulty  in  my 
mind."  In  other  words,  he  contended  only  that  -d  convey- 
ance was  not  a  contract. 

Taking  the  broad  general  language  of  the  clause,  tcJ;ing 
the  equally  general  language  of  the  Federalist,  applying  th« 
principles  of  natural  law,  to  which  he  adhered  and  by  which, 
rather  than  by  the  common  law,  the  wording  of  the  clause 
was  made  intelligible,  Chief  Justice  Marshall  made  his  de- 
cision that  the  contracts  of  the  States  were  protected  from 
impairment.  This  decision  was  generally  acquiesced  in  at 
the  time  and  for  sometime  afterwards.  Even  the  Justices 
who,  in  Ogden  v.  Saunders,  disagreed  with  the  Chief  Jus- 
tice, and  refused  to  go  the  full  length  of  the  natural  law 
theory,  admitted  that  it  was  natural  law  which  chiefly 
created  the  obligation  of  the  contracts  of  the  States  them- 
selves. It  is  by  no  means  certain,  therefore,  that  the  Chief 
Justice  was  not  justified  in  his  belief  that  the  framers  of 
the  Constitution  intended  the  meaning  which  he  gave.  And 
it  is  difficult  to  say  that  he  should  have  argued  that  the 
clause,  so  construed,  would  have  caused  the  rejection  of  the 
Constitution  and  hence  should  not  be  construed  according 
to  what  was,  to  him,  the  plain  meaning  of  its  terms.  It 
remains  to  examine  the  proceedings  of  the  convention  itself. 


663]        AS  VIEWED  BY  FRAMERS  OF  THE  CONSTITUTION      IIQ 

It  was  not  until  slightly  over  two  weeks  before  the  close 
of  the  Convention  that  we  find  any  reference  to  a  provision 
relating  to  contracts.  On  Tuesday,  August  28,  Rufus  King 
moved  to  add  to  the  prohibitions  upon  the  States,  in  the 
words  of  the  Ordinance  of  Congress  establishing  new  States 
— the  Northwest  Ordinance — a  prohibition  on  the  States  to 
interfere  in  private  contracts.  Gouverneur  Morris  thought 
this  would  be  going  too  far,  as  there  are  a  thousand  laws, 
he  said,  relating  to  the  bringing  and  the  limitation  of  actions 
which  affect  contracts.  James  Wilson  was  in  favor  of 
King's  motion.  Madison  admitted  that  inconveniences  might 
arise  from  such  a  prohibition,  but  thought  these  overbal- 
anced by  the  utility  of  it.  He  conceived,  however,  that  a 
negative  on  the  State  laws  could  alone  secure  the  desired 
effect.  Mason  thought  this  carrying  restraint  too  far,  and 
thought  that  cases  might  happen  where  interference  would 
be  necessary,  mentioning  the  case  of  statute  of  limitations. 
Wilson  replied:  "The  answer  to  these  objections  is  that 
retrospective  interference  only  will  be  prohibited."  Madi- 
son asked  if  that  was  not  already  done  by  the  prohibition 
of  ex  post  facto  laws.  This  ended  the  debate,  for  the  pro- 
hibition was  voted  simply  against  ex  post  facto  laws.17  The 
next  day  Dickinson  reported  that,  on  consulting  Blackstone, 
he  found  that  the  term  "  ex  post  facto  "  related  to  criminal 
cases  only  and  would  not,  therefore,  prevent  the  States  from 
passing  retrospective  laws  in  civil  cases.  The  draft  was 
sent  to  the  Committee  of  Style,  however,  on  September  10, 
without  any  change  being  made.  It  was  upon  its  return 
from  this  committee  on  September  12  that  the  "contracts 
clause"  first  made  its  appearance,  the  prohibition  being 
directed  to  the  passage  of  any  laws  "altering  or  impairing 
the  obligation  of  contracts."  An  amendment,  striking  out 
the  word  "altering"  was  passed  on  the  I4th  of  September, 
but  a  motion  by  Gerry,  who  "  entered  into  observation  incul- 
cating the  importance  of  public  faith  and  the  propriety  of 
the  restraint  put  on  the  states  from  impairing  the  obligation 

17  Madison  has  it  in  his  notes,  "  retrospective  "  law. 


I2O  OBLIGATION  OF  CONTRACTS  [664 

of  contracts,"  to  put  Congress  under  the  same  restraint  was 
not  seconded.  There  is,  also,  a  note  found  upon  Mason's 
copy  of  the  draft  of  February  12,  to  the  effect  that  a  mo- 
tion to  strike  out  "  ex  post  facto  laws,"  and,  after  the  words 
"  obligation  of,"  to  insert  "  previous  "  was  refused.  This 
motion  is  not  found  in  the  journal  or  in  any  other  of  the 
records  of  the  debates.18 

It  is  very  plain  that  the  convention  had  in  mind  only 
retrospective  laws  as  impairing  the  obligation  of  contracts, 
and  it  is  almost  equally  plain  that  they  had  in  mind  only  the 
contracts  of  private  individuals. 

18  The  history  of  this  clause  in  the  Convention  is  accurately  de- 
scribed 'by  Meigs  in  his  Growth  of  the  Constitution,  pp.  182-186.  Its 
history  may  easily  be  traced  in  Far  rand's  authoritative  Records  of 
the  Federal  Convention,  t>y  referring  to  the  index  which  gives  the 
places  of  reference  of  each  clause.  A  reference  to  vol.  ii,  pp.  448, 
449,  should  be  added. 


INDEX 


Ames,  31. 

Austin,  theories  of,  30. 

Bank  of  Columbia  v.  Okely,  52, 

105. 

Blackstone,    definition    of    con- 
tract, 24,  33,  36,  66,  71. 
Blair  v.  Chicago,  76. 
Boise  Water  Co.  v.  Boise  City, 

109  (note). 

Borough  franchises,  83  ff. 
Brown's    Austinian    Theory    of 

Law,  quoted,  55. 
Browne's    Civil    and   Admiralty 

Law,  cited,  82. 

Burgess  v.  Seligman,  49  (note). 
Burke,    Edmund,    argument    in 

the  East  India  Company  case, 

85  ff. 

Charles  River  Bridge  case,  103. 

Charters,  corporate,  contractual 
character  of,  58  ff. 

Church  of  Latter  Day  Saints  v. 
United  States,  106  (note). 

Cincinnati  v.  Louisville  &  N.  R. 
Co.,  52  (note). 

Constitutional  Fathers,  doctrines 
of,  in  ff. 

Contract,  definitions  of,  20  ff . 

Contracts,  defined,  17;  Black- 
stone,  24;  Marshall,  25. 

Contracts  between  individuals. 
17- 

Contract  between  States,  17. 

Conveyance,  contractual,  char- 
acter of,  21  ff. 

Corporate  charter,  as  a  contract, 
58  ff. 

Corporation  Act  of  Charles  II, 
81. 

Corporations,  status  of,  as  com- 
mon law,  65. 

Dartmouth  College  Case,  58  ff. 
Dartmouth    College    v.    Wood- 
ward, 16,  47. 


Davis,  Origin  and  Development 
of  Corporations,  quoted,  82 
(note). 

Dillon,  J.  R,  quoted  as  to  value 
of  Dartmouth  College  de- 
cision, 104  (note). 

Doe,  C.  J.,  views  of,  108. 

Douglas  v.  Kentucky,  49. 

East  India  Company,  85. 
Eminent     Domain,     cannot     be 
alienated  by  contract,  52. 

Farmers'  &  Mechanics'  Bank  y. 

Smith,.  17. 
Federalist,    quoted,    112;    cited, 

118. 
Fletcher  v.  Peck,  16,  24,  67,  93, 

102. 

Gelpcke  v.  Dubuque,  50. 

Gifts,  contractual  character  of, 

29. 
Green  v.  Biddle,  17. 

Henry,  Patrick,  112. 

Hobbes,  contract  theories  of,  28. 

Illinois  Central  Ry.  Co.  v.  Illi- 
nois, 52  (note),  105,  109. 

Jefferson  Branch  Bank  v.  Skelly, 

49  (note). 
Johnson,     Justice,     opinion     in 

Ogden  v.  Saunders,  45. 

Kent,  as  to  contractual  character 

of  gifts,  29. 
King  v.  Amery,  36. 
King  v.  Passmore,  65. 
Knoup  v.  Piqua  Bank,  84. 
Kyd,  on  corporations,  71  (note), 

80  (note). 


Life  Insurance  &  T.  Co.  v.  De- 
bolt,  50  (note). 


121 


122 


INDEX 


[666 


Lodge,  Henry  Cabot,  Life  of 
Webster,  quoted,  95. 

McMillan  v.  McNeill,  16. 

Maine,  Sir  Henry,  quoted,  104 
(note). 

Maitland,  32  (note). 

Marshall,  Chief  Justice,  his  defi- 
nition of  contract,  25;  his  use 
of  natural  law,  26  (note)  ;  his 
dissent  in  Ogden  v.  Saunders, 
42 ;  opinion  in  Dartmouth  Col- 
lege Case,  68  ff. 

Martin,  Luther,  113. 

Merriam,  American  Political 
Theories,  quoted,  117. 

Morawetz,  Private  Corporations, 
cited,  107  (note). 

Natural  Law,  regards  convey- 
ance as  a  contract,  26;  in 
opinions  in  Ogden  v.  Saun- 
ders, 42. 

New  Jersey  v.  Wilson,  16. 

Newton  v.  Commissioners,  52. 

Northwest  Ordinance,  114. 

Obligation  of  Contract,  13. 

Obligation,  defined,  17,  20. 

Ogden  y.  Saunders,  17,  40. 

Ohio  Life  Insurance  Co.  v.  De- 
bolt,  51  (note). 

Old  Colony  Trust  Co.  v.  Omaha, 
109  (note). 

Owensboro  v.  Cumberland  Tele- 
phone Co.,  109  (note). 

Owings  v.  Speed,  17. 

Parliament,  British,  and  obliga- 
tion of  contracts,  48;  regula- 
tory power  over  corporations, 
76. 

Piqua  Branch  Bank  v.  Knoup, 
51- 

Police  Power,  cannot  be  alien- 
ated by  contract,  52. 

Powell,  on  contracts,  34  (note). 

Public  corporation,  Dartmouth 
College  a,  91  ff. 


Public  Service  Franchises,  109. 
Pufendorf,  52;  his  doctrine  of 
natural  law,  27  ff .,  47. 

Salmond's  Jurisprudence, quoted, 
54- 

Savigny,  his  definition  of  con- 
tract, 20. 

Shirley,  J.  M.,  The  Dartmouth 
College  Causes,  cited,  18 
(note)  ;  cited  (note)  and  ex- 
amined, 59;  quoted,  99  (note). 

St'ate,  obligation  of,  40 ff.;  as  a 
subject  of  legal  obligation,  53 
ff. ;  suability  of,  54  ff. 

State  contracts,  51. 

Stone  v.  Mississippi,  52  (note), 
103. 

Story,  Justice,  use  by,  of  natural 
law,  46;  opinion  in  Dartmouth 
College  Case,  67,  73;  opinion 
in  Terrett  v.  Taylor,  90;  his 
attitude  in  the  Dartmouth 
College  Case,  100. 

Sturges  v.  Crowninshield,  16,36 
(note). 

Taylor,  on  Corporations,  quoted, 
107  (note). 

Terrett  v.  Taylor,  90. 

Universities,  status  of,  as  public 
corporations,  93. 

Vanhorne's  Lessee  v.  Dorrance, 
"7- 

Wales  v.  Stetson,  90  (note). 

Washington,  Justice,  opinion  in 
Ogden  v.  Saunders,  44;  opin- 
ion in  Dartmouth  College 
Case,  66,  73. 

Webster,  Daniel,  argument  in 
Dartmouth  College  Case,  18, 

95- 
West  River  Bridge  Co.  v.  Dix, 

103. 
Wilson,   James,   36,   37    (note), 

47;  views  of,  89, 


ALBERT  SHAW  LECTURES  ON   DIP- 
LOMATIC  HISTORY 


1899.  JOHN  H.  LATANE.    The  Diplomatic  Relations  of 
the  United  States  and  Spanish  America.    1900. 
(Out  of  print.) 

1900.  JAMES  MORTON  CALLAHAN.     The   Diplomatic 
History   of    the  Southern  Confederacy.     1901. 
(Out  of  print.) 

1906.  JESSE  SIDDALL  REEVES.    American  Diplomacy 
under  Tyler  and  Polk.    1907.    $1.50. 

1907.  ELBERT  JAY  BENTON.    International  Law  and 
Diplomacy  of  the  Spanish-American  War.    1908. 
$1.50. 

1909.    EPHRAIM  DOUGLAS  ADAMS.     British  Interests 
and  Activities  in  Texas,  1838-1846.    1910.  $1.50. 

1911.  CHARLES  OSCAR  PAULLIN.     Diplomatic  Nego- 
tiations of  American  Naval  Officers,  1778-1883. 
1912.     $2.00. 

1912.  ISAAC  J.  Cox.    The  West  Florida  Controversy, 
1798-1813.     1918.     $3.00. 

1913.  WILLIAM  R.  MANNING.    Early  Diplomatic  Re- 
lations between  the  United  States  and  Mexico. 

1916.  $2.25. 

1914.  FRANK  A.  UPDIKE.    The  Diplomacy  of  the  War 
of  1812.     1915.     $2.50. 

1917.    PAYSON  J.  TREAT.    Early  Diplomatic  Relations 
between  the  United  States  and  Japan,  1853-1865. 

1917.  $2.50. 


THE  JOHNS  HOPKINS  PRESS 

BALTIMORE,  MARYLAND 


JOHNS  HOPKINS  UNIVERSITY  STUDIES 

IN 

HISTORICAL  AND  POLITICAL  SCIENCE 

Edited  by  HERBERT  B.  ADAMS,  1882-1901 

•  Not  sold  separately. 
FIRST  SERIES.— 1883.— 94.00. 

(Volume  sold  only  with  complete  set.) 

I.  An  Introduction  to  American  Institutional  History.    By  B.  A.  FREEMAN.     25  cents. 

II.  The  Germanic  Origin  of  New  England  Towns.     By  H.  B.  ADAMS.     DO  cents. 

HI.  Local  Government  in  Illinois.     By  ALBHST  SHAW. — Local  Government  in  Pennsyl- 
vania.    By  E.  R.  L.  GOULD.     SO  cents. 

XT.  Saxon  Tithingmen  in  America.     By  H.  B.  ADAMS.     50  cents. 
T.  Local  Government  in  Michigan  and  the  Northwest.    By  B.  W.  BBMIS.     25  cents. 
TI.  Parish  Institutions  of  Maryland.    By  EDWARD  INGLB.    40  cents. 
•VII.  Old  Maryland  Manors.     By  JOHN  HEMSLEY  JOHNSON. 
VIII.  Norman  Constables  in  America.    By  H.  B.  ADAMS.     50  cents. 
IX -X.  Village  Communities  of  Cape  Ann  and  Salem.    By  H.  B.  ADAMS.     50  cents. 

XI.  The  Genesis  of  a  New  England  State.    By  A.  JOHNSTON.    SO  cents. 
•XII.  Local  Government  and  Schools  in  South  Carolina.     By  B.  J.  RAKAGB. 

SECOND  SERIES.— 1884. 
(Volume  sold  only  with  complete  sets.) 
•I-II.  Methods  of  Eistorioal  Study.    By  H.  B.  ADAMS. 

in.  The  Fast  and  Present  of  Political  Economy.    By  B.  T.  BLT.     85  cents. 
IV.  Samuel  Adams,  the  Man  of  the  Town  Meeting.    By  JAMBS  K.  HOSMKS.     85  cents. 
T-VI.  Taxation  in  the  United  States.    By  HENRY  CARTER  ADAMS.    60  cents. 
yn.  Institutional  Beginnings  in  a  Western  State.    By  JESSE  MACT.     25  cents. 
VIII-IX.  Indian  Money  in  New  England,  etc.     By  WILLIAM  B.  WEBDBN.     50  cents. 
•Z.  Town  and  County  Government  in  the  Colonies.     By  B.  CHANNINO. 
•XI.  Rudimentary  Society  among  Boys.     By  J.  HEMSLEY  JOHNSON. 

XII.  Land  Laws  of  Mining  Districts.    By  C.  H.  SHINN.    60  cents. 

THIRD  SERIES.— 1885.— 94.00. 

Z.  Maryland's  Influence  upon  Land  Cessions  to  the  TJ.  8.    By  H.  B.  ADAMS.    75  cents. 

II-III.  Virginia  Local  Institutions.    By  B.  INGLB.    75  cents. 

IV.  Recent  American  Socialism.     By  RICHARD  T.  BLT.     50  cents. 

Y-yi-VH.  Maryland  Local  Institutions.     By  LEWIS  W.  WIUIBLM.     $1.00. 

TXXZ.  Influence  of  the  Proprietors  in  Founding  New  Jersey.    By  A.  SCOTT.     25  cents. 

IX-X.  American  Constitutions.     By  HORACE  DAVIS.     50  cents. 

XI-XII.  The  City  of  "Washington,    By  J.  A.  PORTER.     50  cents. 

FOURTH  SERIES.— 1886.— $4.00. 

•I.  Dutch  Village  Communities  on  the  Hudson  River.     By  I.  ELTING. 
II-III.  Town  Government  in  Rhode  Island.    By  W.  B.  FOSTER. — The  Narragansett  Plant- 
ers.    By  EDWAED  CHANNINO.     50  cents. 

IV.  Pennsylvania  Boroughs.     By  WILLIAM  P.  HOLCOMB.     50  cents. 

T.  Introduction  to  Constitutional  History  of  the  States.     By  J.  F.  JAMESON.     60  cents. 
VI.  The  Puritan  Colony  at  Annapolis,  Maryland.     By  D.  R.  RANDALL.     60  cents. 
Til  VIII-IX.  The  Land  Question  in  the  United  States.     By  8.  SATO.     $1.00. 
X.  Town  and  City  Government  of  New  Haven.     By  C.  H.  LBVBBMORB.     50  cents. 
XI-XII.  Land  System  of  the  New  England  Colonies.    By  M.  EGLESTON.     50  cents. 

FIFTH  SERIES.— 1887.— $4.00. 

I  II.  City  Government  of  Philadelphia.    By  B.  P.  ALLINSON  and  B.  PBNBOSB.    60  teat*. 

III.  City  Government  of  Boston.    By  JAMBS  M.  BCGBBB.    25  cents. 
•IV.  City  Government  of  St.  Louis.     By  MARSHALL  S.  SNOW. 

V-yi.  Local  Government  in  Canada.    By  JOHN  GEORGE  BOUEINOT.    50  cents. 

VH.  Effect  of  the  War  of  1818  upon  the  American  Union.     By  N.  M.  BUTLBK.     25  cents. 

VIII.  Votes  on  the  Literature  of  Charities.    By  HERBERT  B.  ADAMS.     25  cents. 

IX.  Predictions  of  Hamilton  and  De  Tocqueville.     By  JAMBS  BRYCB.     25  cents. 

X.  The  Study  of  History  in  England  and  Scotland.    By  P.  FEBDBBICQ.    25  cents. 

XI.  Seminary  Libraries  and  University  Extension.    By  H.  B.  ADAMS.     25  cents. 
•XII.  European  Schools  of  History  and  Politics.     By  A.  D.  WHITE. 

SIXTH   SERIES.— 1888.— $4.00. 
The  History  of  Co-operation  in  the  United  States. 

viii 


SEVENTH  SERIES.— 1889. 

(Volume  sold  only  with  complete  set.) 

X.  Arnold  Toynbee.    By  F.  C.  MONTAGUS.    60  cents. 

II-III.  Municipal  Government  In  San  Francisco.     By  BERNARD  MOSES.     50  cents. 

XV.  Municipal  History  of  Mew  Orleans.     By  WM.  W.  HOWE.     25  cents. 

•V-VI.  English  Culture  in  Virginia.     By  WILLIAM  P.  TBBNT. 

TXX-VXXI-XX.  The  River  Towns  of  Connecticut.    By  CHABLES  M.  ANDXBWS.     fl.OO. 

•X-XI-XII.  Federal    Government    in    Canada.      By    JOHN    Q.    BOUBINOT. 

EIGHTH   SERIES.— 1890. 

(Volume  sold  only  with  complete  set.) 

X-XX.  The  Beginnings  of  American  Nationality.     By  A.  W.  SMALL.     $1.00. 

XII.  Local  Government  in  Wisconsin.      By  D.  E.  SPENCER.     25  cents. 

•IV.  Spanish  Colonization  in  the  Southwest.     By  F.  W.  BLACKMAE. 

V-VI.  The  Study  of  History  in  Germany  and  France.    By  P.  FBBDBBICQ.     $1.00. 

YXX-XX.  Progress  of  the  Colored  People  of  Maryland.    By  J.  R.  BBACKBTT.    $1.00. 

•X.  The   Study   of    History    in    Belgium    and   Holland.     By    P.    FBBDBBICQ. 

XI-XII.  Seminary  Motes  on  Historical  Literature.    By  H.  B.  ADAMS  and  others.    50  cents. 

NINTH  SERIES.— 1891. 

(Volume  sold  only  with  complete  set.) 

•I-II.  Government  of  the  United  States.    By  W.  W.  WILLODOHBT  and  W.  F.  WILLODOHBT. 
III-IV.  University   Education   in   Maryland.     By   B.    C.    STBINBB.     The  Johns   Hopkins 

University  (1876-1891).     By  D.  C.  OILMAN.     50  cents. 
•V-VL  Municipal  Unity  in  the  Lombard  Communes.     By  W.  K.  WILLIAMS. 
VII-VIII.  Public  Lands  of  the  Roman  Republic.    By  A.  STEPHENSON.     75  cents. 
XX.  Constitutional  Development  of  Japan.    By  T.  IYENAQA.    50  cents. 
•X.  A  History  of  Liberia.     By  J.  H.  T.  Mcl'HEBSON. 
XX-XXX.  The  Indian  Trade  in  Wisconsin.    By  F.  J.  TUBNEB,    60  cents. 

TENTH  SERIES.— 1892.— $4.00. 

X.  The  Bishop  Hill  Colony.    By  MICHAEL  A.  MIKKELSEN.     50  cents. 

XI-XII.     Church  and  State  in  Mew  England.    By  PADL  E.  LADBB.     50  cents. 

XV.  Church  and  State  in  Maryland.    By  OBOBQB  PBTBIB.    50  cents. 

V-VI.  Religions  Development  of  Morth  Carolina.     By  8.  B.  WEEKS.     60  cents. 

YXI.  Maryland's  Attitude  in  the  Struggle  for  Canada.    By  J.  W.  BLACK.     50  cents. 

VI11-XX.  The  Quakers  in  Pennsylvania.     By  A.  C.  APPLBOABTH.     75  cents. 

X-XI.  Columbus  and  his  Discovery  of  America.    By  H.  B.  ADAMS  and  H.  Woo».    50  cent*. 

XXX.  Causes  of  the  American  Revolution.     By  J.  A.  WOODBDBN.    50  cents. 

ELEVENTH  SERIES.— 1893.— $4.00. 

X.  The  Social  Condition  of  Labor.    By  E.  R.  L.  OODLD.    50  cents. 
XX.  The  World's  Representative  Assemblies  of  To-Day.    By  E.  EL  ALDEN.     50  cents. 
III-IV.  The  Negro  in  the  District  of  Columbia.    By  EDWARD  INGLE.     $1.00. 
V-YI.  Church  and  State  in  North  Carolina.    By  STBPHBN  B.  WEEKS.     50  cents. 
VII-VIII.  The  Condition  of  the  Western  Farmer,  etc.    By  A.  F.  BENTLEY.    $1.00. 
IX-X.  History  of  Slavery  in  Connecticut.    By  BERNARD  C.  STEINBB.    75  cents. 
XX-XXX.  Local  Government  in  the  South.    By  B.  W.  BBMIS  and  others.    $1.00. 

TWELFTH   SERIES.— 1894.— $4.00. 

X-XX.  The   Cincinnati    Southern   Railway.     By    J.    H.    HOLJANDEB.     $1.00. 

XXL  Constitutional  Beginnings  of  Morth  Carolina.    By  J.  8.  BABBITT.    50  cents. 

XV.  Straggle  of  Dissenters  for  Toleration  in  Virginia.    By  H.  R.  MC!LWAINB.     50  cent* 

V-VI-VTI.  The  Carolina  Pirates  and  Colonial  Commerce.     By  S.  C.  HDOHBON.     $1.00. 

Vlll-XX.  Representation  and  Suffrage  in  Massachusetts.     By  Q.  H.  HAYNBS.     50  cents. 

X.  English  Institutions  and  the  American  Indian.    By  J.  A.  JAMBS.     25  cents. 

XI-XII.  International  Beginnings  of  the  Congo  Free  State.    By  J.  8.  REHYBS.    50  cents. 

THIRTEENTH  SERIES.— 1895.— $4.00. 

X-XX.  Government  of  the  Colony  of  South  Carolina,    By  E.  L.  WHITNEY.     75  cents. 
III-IV.  Early  Relations  of  Maryland  and  Virginia.    By  J.   H.   LATANB.     50   cents. 
V.  The  Rife  of  the  Bicameral  System  in  America.    By  T.  F.  MOBAN.    50  cents. 
VI-VTI.  White  Servitude  in  the  Colony  of  Virginia.    By  J.  C.  BALLAOH.    50  cents. 
VIII.  The  Genesis  of  California's  First  Constitution.     By  R.  D.  HUNT.     50  cents. 
XX.  Benjamin  Franklin  as  an  Economist.     By  W.  A.  WBTZBI.     50  cents. 
X.  The  Provisional  Government  of  Maryland.     By  J.  A.  SILVER.     56  cents. 
XX-XXX.  Government  and  Religion  of  the  Virginia  Indians.    By  S.  R.  HENDBEN.    50  cents. 

FOURTEENTH  SERIES.— 1896.— $4-00. 

X.  Constitutional  History  of  Hawaii.    By  HBNBY  E.  CHAMBERS.    25  cents. 

II.  City  Government  of  Baltimore.     By  THADDBDS  P.  THOMAS.     25  cents. 

III.  Colonial  Origins  of  Mew  England  Senates.     By  F.  L.  RILBY.     50  cents. 
IV-V.  Servitude  in  the  Colony  of  North  Carolina.     By  .1.  S.  BASSBTT.     50  cents. 
VI-VII.  Representation  in  Virginia.     By  J.  A.  C.  CHANDLBB.     50  cents. 

VIII.  History  of  Taxation  in  Connecticut  (1636-1776).      By  F.  R.  JONES.     50  cents. 
XX-X.  A  Study  of  Slavery  in  Mew  Jersey.    By  HBNBY  S.  COOLEY.     50  cents. 
XI-XII.  Causes  of  the  Maryland  Revolution  of  1689.    By  F.  B.  SPARKS.    60  cents. 


FIFTEENTH  SERIES.— 1897.— $4.00. 

X-IZf  The  Tobacco  Industry  in  Virginia  since  1860.    By  B.  W.  ARNOLD.     50  cents. 
XZI-Y.  Street  Hallway  System  of  Philadelphia.     By  P.  W.  SPEIBS.     75  cent!. 
VI.  Daniel  Raymond.     By  C.   P.   NBILL.     50  cents. 
VII-VIII.  Economic  History  of  B.  &  0.  R.  R.     By  M.  REIZENSTEIN.     50  cents. 

IX.  The  South  American  Trade  of  Baltimore.     By  P.  K.  RCTTEB,     50  cents. 
X-XI.  State  Tax  Commissions  in  the  United  States.    By  J.  W.  CHAPMAN.     50  cent*. 
XII.  Tendencies  in  American  Economic  Thought.     By  S.  SIIEBWOOD.     25  cents. 

SIXTEENTH  SERIES.— 1898.— $4.00. 

I-XT.  The  Neutrality  of  the  American  Lakes,  etc.    By  J.  M.  CALLAHAN.    f  1.25.    Cloth,  |1.60. 

V.  West  Florida.     By  H.  E.  CHAMBERS.     25  cents. 

VI.  Anti-Slavery  Leaders  of  North  Carolina,     By  J.  S.  BASSETT.     50  cents. 
VII-IX.  Life  and  Administration  of  Sir  Robert  Eden.    By  B.  C.  STEINEB.     $1.00. 

X-XI.  The  Transition  of  North  Carolina  from  a  Colony.     By  B.   W.  SIKBB.     60  cent*. 
XII.  Jared  Sparks  and  Alexis  D«  Tocqueville.    By  H.  B.  ADAMS.    25  cents. 

SEVENTEENTH  SERIES.— 1899.— $4.00. 

I-II-III.  History  of  State   Banking  in   Maryland.     By   A.   C.    BBYAN.     $1.00. 
IV-V.  The  Know-Nothing  Party  in  Maryland.    By  L.  P.  SCBMECKEBIBB.    75  cents. 
TL  The  Labadlst  Colony  in  Maryland.    By  B.  B.  JAMES.     50  cents. 
VII-VIII.  History  of  Slavery  in  North  Carolina.    By  J.  8.  BASSETT.    75  cents. 
XX-X-XI.  Development  of  the  Chesapeake  ft  Ohio  Canal.     By  O.  W.  WARD.     75  cent*. 
XII.  Public  Educational  Work  in  Baltimore.    By  HBBBBBT  B.  ADAMS.    25  cents. 

EIGHTEENTH  SERIES.— 1900.— $4.00. 

X-XV.  Studies  In  State  Taxation.    Edited  by  J.  H.  HOLLANDKB.    Paper,  $1.00 ;  cloth, 
V-VI.  The  Colonial  Executive  Prior  to  the  Restoration.    By  P.  L.  KAYB.    60  cents. 
TH.  Constitution  and  Admission  of  Iowa  into  the  Union.     By  J.  A.  JAMBS.    30  cents. 
VIII  IX.  The  Church  and  Popular  Education.    By  H.  B.  ADAMS.     50  cents. 
X-XII.  Religious  Freedom  in  Virginia:  Tha  Baptists.    By  W.  T.  THOM.     75  cents. 

NINETEENTH  SERIES.— 1901.— $4.00. 

X-m.  America  In  the  Pacific  and  the  Far  East.    By  J.  M.  CALLAHAN.    75  cents. 
IV-V.  State  Activities  in  Relation  to  Labor.    By  W.  F.  WILLOUGHBT.    50  cents. 
VI- Vn.  History  of  Suffrage  in  Virginia.    By  J.  A.  C.  CHANDLBB.     50  cents. 
TIII-IX.  The  Maryland  Constitution  of  1861.    By  W.  8.  MTBBS.     50  cents. 

X.  Life  of  Commissary  James  Blair.     By  D.  E.  MOTLEY,     25  cents. 

XI-XII.  Gcv.  Hicks  of  Maryland  and  the  Civil  War.    By  Q.  L.  RABCLIBTB.    60  cents. 

TWENTIETH   SERIES.— 1902.— $4.00. 

I.  Western  Maryland  in  the  Revolution.     By  B.  C.  STEINBB.     80  cents. 

II-III.  State  Banks  since  the  National  Bank  Act.    By  O.  E.  BABNETT.     50  cents. 

XV.  Early  History  of  Internal  Improvements  In  Alabama.     By  W.  E.  MABTIN.     80  cent*. 

•V-VI.  Trust  Companies  in  the  United  States.     By  GBOBOB  CATOB. 

YIX-VIII.  The  Maryland  Constitution  of  1851.     By  J.  W.  HARBT.     50  cents. 

XX-X.  Political  Activities  of  Philip  Frenean.     By  8.  E.  POBMAN.     50  cents. 

XI.-XII.  Continental  Opinion  on  a  Middle  European  Tariff  Union.    By  0.  M.  FIBS.    80  eta. 

TWENTY-FIRST  SERIES.— 1903.— $4.00. 

•X-XX.  The  Wabash  Trade  Route.    By  E.  J.  BENTON. 

XXX-XV.  Internal  Improvements  in  North  Carolina.     By  C.  C.  WEAVES.     50  cents. 

V.  History  of  Japanese  Paper  Currency.     By  M.  TAKAKI.     30  cents. 

VI- VII.  Economics   and   Politics   In   Maryland,    1720-1760,    and   the   Public    Services   sf 

Daniel  Dulany  the  Elder.    By  ST.  Q.  L.  SIOUSSAT.    50  cents. 
•VIII-IX  X.  Beginnings  of  Maryland,   1631-1639.     By  B.  C.  STEINEB. 
XI-XII.  The  English  Statutes  In  Maryland.    By  ST.  G.  L.  SIODSSAT.    50  cents. 

TWENTY-SECOND  SERIES.— 1904.— $4.00. 

X-XI.  A  Trial  Bibliography  of  American  Trade-Union  Publications.    50  cents. 

III-IV.  White  Servitude  in  Maryland,  1634-1620,     By  E.  I.  McCoBMAC.    50  cents. 

V.  Switzerland  at  the  Beginning  of  the  Sixteenth  Century.    By  J.  M.  VINCENT.     30  cents. 

VI-VII  VIII.  The  History  of  Reconstruction  in  Virginia.    By  H.  J.  ECKBNHODB.    50  cents. 

XX-X.  The  Foreign  Commerce  of  Japan  since  the  Restoration.     By  Y.  HATTORI.    50  cents. 

XI-XH.  Descriptions  of  Maryland.     By  B.  C.  STEINEB.     50  cents. 

TWENTY-THIRD  SERIES.— 1905.— $4.00. 

X-XI.  Reconstruction  in  South  Carolina.    By  J.  P.  HOTJ.IS.     50  cents. 

III-IV.  State  Government  in  Maryland,  1777-1781.     By  B.  W.  BOND,  JB.     60  cents. 

V-VI.  Colonial  Administration  under  Lord  Clarendon,  1660-1667.    By  P.  L.  KAYB.     50  cts, 

VII-VIII.  Justice  in  Colonial  Virginia.    By  O.  P.  CHITWOOD.     60  cents. 

XX-X.  The  Napoleonic  Exiles  in  America,  1816-1819.    By  J.  S.  REBVBS.     60  cents. 

XX-XXX.  Municipal  Problems  In  Mediaeval  Switzerland.    By  J.  M.  VINCENT.  60  cents. 


TWENTY-FOURTH  SERIES.— igo6.-44.oo. 

I-II.  Spanish-American  Diplomatic  Relations  before  1898.  By  H.  B.  FLACK.  60  cents. 
III-IV.  The  Finances  of  American  Trade  Unions.  By  A.  M.  SAKOLSKI.  75  cents. 
V-VI.  Diplomatic  Negotiations  of  the  United  States  with  Russia.  By  J.  C.  HILDT.  60  cts. 
VII-VIII.  State  Bights  and  Parties  in  North  Carolina,  1776-1831.  By  H.  M.  WAOBTAFF.  60c, 
IX-X.  National  Labor  Federations  in  the  United  States.  By  WILLIAM  KIRK.  76  cents. 
XI -XII.  Maryland  During  the  English  Civil  Wars.  Part  I.  By  B.  C.  STBINBB.  60  cents. 

TWENTY-FIFTH    SERIES.— 1907.— $4.00. 

X.  Internal  Taxation  in  the  Philippines.     By  JOHN  S.  HOED.     30  cents. 
II-III.  The  Monroe  Mission  to  France,  1794-1796.     By  B.  W.  BOND,  Jr.     50  cents. 
XV-V.  Maryland  Daring  the  English  Civil  Wars,  Part  II.    By  BERNARD  C.  STBINJSR.     60e. 
VX-VH.  The  State  in  Constitutional  and  International  Law.     By  R.  T.  CRANH.     60  cents. 
V1I1-IX-X.  Financial  History  of  Maryland,  1789-1848.     By  HUGH  S.  HANNA.     75  cents. 
•XI-X1T.  Apprenticeship  in  American  Trade  Unions.     By  J.  M.  MOTLEY. 

TWENTY-SIXTH  SERIES.— 1908.— $4.00. 

X-XXX.  British  Committees,   Commissions,   and  Councils  of  Trade  and  Plantations,   168ft- 

1675.     By  C.  M.  ANDREWS.     75  cents. 
XV-VI.  Neutral  Rights  and  Obligations  in  the  Anglo-Boer  War.    By  R.  Q.  CAMPBELL. 

75  cents. 
VII- Vin.  The  Elizabethan  Parish  in  its  Ecclesiastical  and  Financial  Aspects.     By  S.  L. 

WARE.     50  cents. 
IX-X.  A  Study  of  the  Topography  and  Municipal  History  of  Praeneste.    By  R.  V.  D. 

MAGOPFIN.     50  cents. 
XI-XIZ.  Beneficiary  Features  of  American  Trade  Unions.    By  J.  B.  KBNNBDT.     50  cents. 

TWENTY-SEVENTH   SERIES.— 1909.— $4.00. 

I-II.  The  Self -Rsoons traction  of  Maryland,  1864-1867.     By  W.  S.  MYEBS.     60  cents. 
XXX-XV-V.  The    Development    of   the    English    Law    of    Conspiracy.     By    J.    W.    BBTAX. 

75  cents. 

VX-VII.  Legislative    and    Judicial    History    of    the    Fifteenth    Amendment.     By    J.    If. 

MATBBWS.     75  cents ;  cloth  $1. 
TUI-XII.  England  and  the  French  Revolution,  1789-1797.     By  W.  T.  LAPBADH,     $1. 

TWENTY-EIGHTH  SERIES.— 1910.— $4.00. 
(Complete  In  four  numbers.) 

X.  History  of  Reconstruction  in  Louisiana   (Through  1868).     By  J.  R.  FlCKLBlf.     $1.00; 

cloth  $1.26. 

XX.  The  Trade  Union  Label.     By  E.  R.  SPEDDEN.     50  cents ;  cloth  75  cents. 
III.  Ths  Doctrine  of  Non-Suability  of  the  Stats  in  ths  United  States.     By   K.   SIXOB- 

WAU>.     60  cents :  cloth  75  cents. 
XV.  David  Rlcardo:  A  Centenary  Estimate.      By  J.  H.  HOLLANDS*.     $1.00;  cloth  $1.26. 

TWENTY-NINTH   SERIES.— 1911.— $4.00. 
(Complete  in  three  numbers.) 

I.  Maryland  Under  ths  Commonwealth:  A  Chronicle  of  the  years  1640-1668.     By  B.  C 

STBINBK.     $1;  cloth  $1.25. 
XX.  The  Dutch  Republie  and  the  American  Revolution.     By  FHIEDRICH   HDLBB.     $1.10; 

cloth  $1.75. 
•III.  The  Closed  Shop  in  American  Trade  Unions.     By  F.  T.  STOCKTON. 

THIRTIETH  SERIES.— 1912.— $4.00. 
(Complete  In  three  numbers.) 

L  Recent  Administration  in  Virginia.     By  F.  A.  MAOHUDEB,     $1.25;  cloth  $1.50. 

n.  The   Standard  Rats  in   America    Trade   Unions.     By    D.   A.    McCABB.     $1.25;    doth 

$1.50. 
XXX.  Admission  to  American  Trade  Unions.     By  F.  B.  WOLFE.     $1.00;  cloth  $1.25. 

THIRTY-FIRST  SERIES.— 1913.— $4-oo. 
(Complete  In  four  numbers.) 

L  Ths  Land  System  in  Maryland,  1780-1765.     By  CLARBNCE  P.  GOULD.     75  cents;  doth 

$1.00. 

XX.  The  Government  of  American  Trade  Unions.  By  T.  W.  OLOCKKR,  $1.00 ;  cloth  $1.28. 
III.  The  Free  Negro  In  Virginia,  1619-1865.  By  J.  H.  RUSSELL.  $1.00 ;  cloth  $1.28. 
XV.  The  Qninqneaaales :  As.  Historical  Study.  By  R.  V.  D.  MAOOITIN.  80  cants;  clwth 

76  cents. 

xi 


THIRTY-SECOND   SERIES.— 1914.— $4.00. 
(Complete  in  three  number*.) 

I.  Jurlidlotlon    In    American    Building-Trades    Unions.    By    N.    R.    WHITXBT.     $1.00: 

elotb  |1.26. 

II.  Slavery  in  Missouri,  1804-1868.     By  H.  A.  TRBXLBB.    |1.25;  cloth  $1.60. 
in,  Colonial  Trade  of  Maryland.     By  M.  8.  MOBKISB.    $1.00 ;  cloth  |1.26. 

THIRTY-THIRD  SERIES.— 1915.— $4.00. 
(Complete  in  Hoar  numbers.) 

I.  Money    and   Transportation   in   Maryland,    1720-1765.    By    CLABENCB    P.    GODLD.     76 

cents;  cloth  $1.00. 

II.  The  Financial  Administration  of  the  Colony  of  Virginia.     By  PBBCY  SCOTT  FLIPPIS 

60  cents;  cloth  76  cents. 
in.  The   Helper   and   American   Trade  Unions.     By   JOHN   H.   ASHWOBTH.     76   cents; 

cloth  $1.00. 
XT.  The  Constitutional  Doctrines  of  Justice  Harlan.     By  FLOYD  BABZILIA  CLARK.     $1.00 ; 

cloth  $1.26. 

THIRTY-FOURTH   SERIES.— 1916.— $4.00. 
(Complete  la  four  numbers.) 

I.  The  Boycott  in  American  Trade  Unions.    By  LEO  WOLMAN.     $1.00 ;  cloth,  $1.26. 

II.  The  Postal  Power  of  Congress.    By  LINDSAY  ROGKBS.     $1.00;  cloth,  $1.26. 

IH.  The  Control  of  Strikes  in  American  Trade  Unions.    By  G.   M.  JANES.     76  cents: 

cloth.  $1.00. 
XT.  State  Administration  in  Maryland.    By  JOHN  L.  DONALDSON.     $1.00;  cloth  $1.26. 

THIRTY-FIFTH  SERIES.— 1917.— $4.00. 
(Complete  In  three  numbers.) 

I.  The  Virginia  Committee  System  and  the  American  Revolution.     By  J.  M.  LBAXB. 

$1.00;  cloth  $1.25. 

II.  The  Organisahllity  of  Labor.     By  W.  O.  WEYFOBTH.     $1.60;  cloth  $1.75. 

m.  Party  Organization  and  Machinery  In  Michigan  since  1890.     By  A.  C.  MILLSPACQH. 
$1.00 ;  cloth  $1.25. 

THIRTY-SIXTH  SERIES.— 1918.— $4.00. 

(Complete  in  four  numbers.) 

I.  The  Standard  of  Living  in  Japan.     By  K.  MOKIMOTO.     $1.25;  cloth  $1.50. 
n.  Sumptuary  Law  in  NUrnberg.    By   K.   R.   GKEENFIBLD.     $1.25;   cloth   $1.50. 
in.  The    Privileges    and    Immunities    of    State    Citizenship.     By    R.    HOWELU     $1.00; 

cloth  $1.25. 
IV.  French  Protestantism,   1559-1562.     By  C.   G.   KELLY.     $1.25;   cloth   $1.50. 

THIRTY-SEVENTH  SERIES.— 1919.     (Incomplete.) 

I.  Unemployment  and  American  Trade  Unions.     By  D.  P.   SMKLSEB,  JK.     $1.25;  cloth 

$1.50. 

II.  The  Labor  Law  of  Maryland.     By  M.  H.  LAncHBiMKR.     $1.25 ;  cloth  $1.50. 

The  set  of  thirty-six  series  of  Studies  is  offered,  uniformly  bound  in  cloth,  for  library 

use  for  $144.00  net.     The  separate  volumes  may  also  be  had  bound  in 

cloth  at  the  prices  stated. 


MOTES   SUPPLEMENTARY   TO   THE   STUDIES    IN    HISTORY 
AND  POLITICS. 

PBICB    Or  THBSB    NOTBS,    TUN    CENTS    NET    BACH,    UNLBSS    OTHBKWISB    STATED. 

Municipal  Government  in  England.     By  ALBEET  SHAW. 
fotlal  Work  In  Australia  and  London.     By  WILLIAM  ORBY. 
Encouragement  of  Higher  Education.    By  H.  B.  ADAMS. 
The  Problem  of  City  Government.     By  SETII  Low. 
Work  Among  the  Working-women  of  Baltimore.     By  H.  B.  ADAMS. 

Charities:   The  Relation  of  the  State,  the  City,  and  the  Individual  to  Modern  Philan- 
thropic Work.     By  A.  Q.  WAKNBB. 
Law  ana  History.     By  WALTER  B.  SCA.IFB. 

The  Weeds  of  Self-Supporting  Women.     By  CLARB  DB  GUAFFHNEBID. 
Early  Presbyterian!  sm  in  Maryland.     By  J.  W.  MclLVAiN. 
The  Educational  Aspect  of  the  U.  8.  National  Museum.     By  O.  T.  MASON. 
University  Extension  and  the  University  of  the  Future.    By  RICHABD  Q.  MOULTOW. 
The  Philosophy  of  Education.    By  WILLIAM  T.  HARRIS. 
Popular  Election  of  U.  S.  Senators.     By  JOHN  HAYNES. 
A  Memorial  of  Lucius  S.  Merrlam.    By  J.  H.  HOLLANDER  and  others. 
Is  History  Past  Politics!     By  HERBERT  B.  ADAMS. 

Lay  Sermons.    By  AMOS  G.  WABNBB  ;  with  a  biographical  sketch  by  GBOBGB  B.  How  A** 
Price  twenty-five  cents. 


253 


FEB  -  2  1969 


f 


PLEASE  DO  NOT  REMOVE 
CARDS  OR  SLIPS  FROM  THIS  POCKET 

UNIVERSITY  OF  TORONTO  LIBRARY