Skip to main content

Full text of "United States census of agriculture: 1954"

See other formats


cK9 


o(\S\rLAVJ^3 


"Bi 


Given  By 

37.  S,  SUPT.  OF  DOCUMENTS 


\H>05IT( 


^OCITORY 


M- 


Vol.  Ill  -  pt.  9    ch.  IX 


FARMERS  AND  FARM  PRODUC 
IN  THE  UNITED  STATES 

(A  COOPERATIVE  REPORT) 


sa  m&i?*?. 


"/n\ 


Agricultural  Producers  and  Production 
in  the  United  States— A  General  View 


SPECIAL  REPORTS 


1954 

Census 

of 

Agriculture 


U.  S.  DEPARTMENT  OF  COMMERCE 

BUREAU  OF  THE  CENSUS 


U.  S.  DEPARTMENT  OF  AGRICULTURE 

AGRICULTURAL  RESEARCH  SERVICE 
WASHINGTON  •   7956 


It      ii!zl 


U.  S.  Department  of  Agriculture 

Ezra  Taft  Benson,  Secretary 

Agricultural  Research  Service 

Byron  T.  Shaw,  Administrator 

U.  S.  Department  of  Commerce 

Sinclair  Weeks,  Secretary 

Bureau  of  the  Census 

Robert  W.  Burgess,  Director 


United  States 

Census 

of 

Agriculture: 

1954 

Volume   III 
SPECIAL  REPORTS 

Part    9 

Farmers  and  Farm  Production  in  the  United  States 

(A   Cooperative   Report) 


Chapter  IX 

Agricultural  Producers  and 
Production   in   the   United 
States — A  General  View 


CHARACTERISTICS  OF  FARMERS  and  FARM  PRODUCTION 
PRINCIPAL  TYPES  OF  FARMS    • 


BUREAU  OF  THE  CENSUS 
Robert  W.  Burgess,  Director 


AGRICULTURE  DIVISION 
Ray  Hurley,  Chief 
Warder  B.  Jenkins,  Assistant  Chief 


AGRICULTURAL  RESEARCH  SERVICE 
Byron  T.  Shaw,  Administrator 


FARM  AND  LAND  MANAGEMENT  RESEARCH 

Sherman  E.  Johnson,  Director 


PRODUCTION  ECONOMICS   RESEARCH   BRANCH 
Carl  P.  Heisig,  Chief 


Boston  Public  Library 
Superintendent  of  Documents 

OCT  3  - 1957 


+W7.3I*3 

I/,  3 

eh? 


SUGGESTED  IDENTIFICATION 

U.  S.  Bureau  of  the  Census.      U.  S.  Census  of  Agriculture.- 1954.     Vol.  Ill,  Special  Repor 

Part  9,  Farmers  and  Farm  Production  in  the  United  States. 

Chapter  IX,  Agricultural  Producers  and  Production  in  the  United  States— A  General  Vi 

U.  S.  Government  Printing  Office,  Washington  25,  D.  C,  1956. 


For  sale  by  the  Superintendent  of  Documents,  U.  S.  Government  Printing  Office,  Washington  25,  D.  C. 
or  any  of  the  Field  Offices  of  the  Department  of  Commerce,  Price  40  cents  (paper  cover) 


PREFACE 


The  purpose  of  this  report  is  to  present  an  analysis  of  the  characteristics  of  farmers  and  farm  production 
for  the  most  important  types  of  farms  as  shown  by  data  for  the  1954  Census  of  Agriculture.  The  analysis 
deals  with  the  relative  importance,  pattern  of  resource  use,  some  measures  of  efficiency,  and  problems  of 
adjustment  and  change  for  the  principal  types  of  farms. 

The  data  given  in  the  various  chapters  of  this  report  have  been  derived  largely  from  the  special  tabula- 
tion of  data  for  each  type  of  farm,  by  economic  class,  for  the  1954  Census  of  Agriculture.  The  detailed 
statistics  for  each  type  of  farm  for  the  United  States  and  the  principal  subregions  appear  in  Part  8  of  Volume 
III  of  the  reports  for  the  1954  Census  of  Agriculture. 

This  cooperative  report  was  prepared  under  the  direction  of  Ray  Hurley,  Chief  of  the  Agriculture  Divi- 
sion of  the  Bureau  of  the  Census,  U.  S.  Department  of  Commerce,  and  Kenneth  L.  Bachman,  Head,  Produc- 
tion, Income,  and  Costs  Section,  Production  Economics  Research  Branch,  Agricultural  Research  Service  of 
the  U.  S.  Department  of  Agriculture. 

Jackson  V.  McElveen,  Agricultural  Economist,  Production,  Income,  and  Costs  Section,  Production 
Economics  Research  Branch,  Agricultural  Research  Service  of  the  U.  S.  Department  of  Agriculture,  super- 
vised a  large  part  of  the  detailed  planning  and  analysis  for  the  various  chapters. 


The  list  of  chapters  and  the  persons  preparing  each  chapter  i 


Chapter  I Wheat     Producers    and     Wheat 

Production 
A.  W.  Epp, 

University  of  Nebraska. 


Chapter  II_ 


Chapter  ITT 


Chapter  IV_ 


Chapter  V. 


Cotton    Producers    and    Cotton 

Production 
Robert  B.  Glasgow, 
Production   Economics  Research 

Branch, 
Agricultural  Research  Service, 
United    States    Department     of 

Agriculture. 

Tobacco  and   Peanut   Producers 

and  Production 
R.  E.  L.  Greene, 
University  of  Florida. 

Poultry  Producers   and    Poultry 

Production 
William  P.  Mortenson, 
University  of  Wisconsin. 

Dairy  Producers  and  Dairy  Pro- 
duction 
P.  E.  McNall, 
University  of  Wisconsin. 


Chapter  VI. 


Chapter  VII. 


Chapter  VIII. 


Chapter  IX, 


The  editorial  work  for  this  report  was  performed  by  Caroline  B.  Sher 
statistical  tables  was  supervised  by  Margaret  Wood. 

December  1956 


Western  Stock  Ranches  and  Live- 
stock Farms 

Mont  H.  Saunderson, 

Western  Ranching  and  Lands 
Consultant, 

Bozeman,  Mont. 

Cash-grain  and  Livestock  Pro- 
ducers in  the  Corn  Belt 

Edwin  G.  Strand, 

Production  Economics  Research 
Branch, 

Agricultural  Research  Service, 

United  States  Department  of 
Agriculture. 

Part-time  Farming 
H.  G.  Halcrow, 
University  of  Connecticut. 

Agricultural  Producers  and  Pro- 
duction in  the  United  States — 
A  General  View 

Jackson  V.  McElveen, 

Production  Economics  Research 
Branch, 

Agricultural  Research  Service, 

United  States  Department  of 
Agriculture. 

i,  and  the  preparation  of  the 


UNITED  STATES  CENSUS  OF  AGRICULTURE:  1954 
REPORTS 


Volume  I. — Counties  and  State  Economic  Areas.  Statistics  for  counties  include  number  of  farms,  acreage,  value,  and  farm  operators; 
farms  by  color  and  tenure  of  operator;  facilities  and  equipment;  use  of  commercial  fertilizer;  farm  labor;  farm  expenditures;  livestock  and 
livestock  products;  specified  crops  harvested;  farms  classified  by  type  of  farm  and  by  economic  class;  and  value  of  products  sold  by  source. 

Data  for  State  economic  areas  include  farms  and  farm  characteristics  by  tenure  of  operator,  by  type  of  farm,  and  by  economic  class. 

Volume  I  is  published  in  33  parts. 

Volume  H. — General  Report.  Statistics  by  Subjects,  United  States  Census  of  Agriculture,  1954.  Summary  data  and  analyses  of 
the  data  for  States,  for  Geographic  Divisions,  and  for  the  United  States  by  subjects. 


Volume  III. — Special  Reports 

Part  1. — Multiple-Unit  Operations.  This  report  will  be  similar  to 
Part  2  of  Volume  V  of  the  reports  for  the  1950  Census  of  Agri- 
culture. It  will  present  statistics  for  approximately  900 
counties  and  State  economic  areas  in  12  Southern  States  and 
Missouri  for  the  number  and  characteristics  of  multiple-unit 
operations  and  farms  in  multiple  units. 

Part  2.— Ranking  Agricultural  Counties.  This  special  report  will 
present  statistics  for  selected  items  of  inventory  and  agricul- 
tural production  for  the  leading  counties  in  the  United  States. 

Part  3.— Alaska,  Hawaii,  Puerto  Rico,  District  of  Columbia,  and 
U.  S.  Possessions.  These  areas  were  not  included  in  the  1954 
Census  of  Agriculture.  The  available  current  data  from  vari- 
ous Government  sources  will  be  compiled  and  published  in 
this  report. 

Part  4. — Agriculture,  1954,  a  Graphic  Summary.  This  report  will 
present  graphically  some  of  the  significant  facts  regarding 
agriculture  and  agricultural  production  as  revealed  by  the  1954 
Census  of  Agriculture. 

Part  5.— Farm-Mortgage  Debt.  This  will  be  a  cooperative  study 
by  the  Agricultural  Research  Service  of  the  U.  S.  Department 
of  Agriculture  and  the  Bureau  of  the  Census.  It  will  present, 
by  States,  data  based  on  the  1954  Census  of  Agriculture  and  a 
special  mail  survey  conducted  in  January  1956,  on  the  num- 
ber of  mortgaged  farms,  the  amount  of  mortgage  debt,  and  the 
amount  of  debt  held  by  principal  lending  agencies. 

Part  6. — Irrigation  in  Humid  Areas.  This  cooperative  report  by 
the  Agricultural  Research  Service  of  the  U.  S.  Department  of 
Agriculture  and  the  Bureau  of  the  Census  will  present  data  ob- 
tained by  a  mail  survey  of  operators  of  irrigated  farms  in  28 
States  on  the  source  of  water,  method  of  applying  water,  num- 
ber of  pumps  used,  acres  of  crops  irrigated  in  1954  and  1955, 
the  number  of  times  each  crop  was  irrigated,  and  the  cost  of 
irrigation  equipment  and  the  irrigation  system. 

Part  7. — Popular  Report  of  the  1954  Census  of  Agriculture.  This 
report  is  planned  to  be  a  general,  easy-to-read  publication  for 
the  general  public  on  the  status  and  broad  characteristics  of 
United  States  agriculture.  It  will  seek  to  delineate  such  as- 
pects of  agriculture  as  the  geographic  distribution  and  dif- 
ferences by  size  of  farm  for  such  items  as  farm  acreage,  princi- 
pal crops,  and  important  kinds  of  livestock,  farm  facilities, 
farm  equipment,  use  of  fertilizer,  soil  conservation  practices, 
farm  tenure,  and  farm  income. 

Part  8. — Size  of  Operation  by  Type  of  Farm.  This  will  be  a  coop- 
erative special  report  to  be  prepared  in  cooperation  with  the 
Agricultural  Research  Service  of  the  U.  S.  Department  of  Agri- 
culture.    This  report  will  contain  data  for  119  economic  sub- 


regions  (essentially  general  type-of-farming  areas)  showing  the 
general  characteristics  for  each  type  of  farm  by  economic  class. 
It  will  provide  data  for  a  current  analysis  of  the  differences 
that  exist  among  groups  of  farms  of  the  same  type.  It  will 
furnish  statistical  basis  for  a  realistic  examination  of  produc- 
tion of  such  commodities  as  wheat,  cotton,  and  dairy  products 
in  connection  with  actual  or  proposed  governmental  policies 
and  programs. 
Part  9. — Farmers  and  Farm  Production  in  the  United  States. 
The  purpose  of  this  report  is  to  present  an  analysis  of  the 
characteristics  of  farmers  and  farm  production  for  the  most 
important  types  of  farms  as  shown  by  data  for  the  1954  Census 
of  Agriculture.  The  analysis  deals  with  the  relative  importance, 
pattern  of  resource  use,  some  measures  of  efficiency,  and  prob- 
lems of  adjustment  and  change  for  the  principal  types  of  farms. 
The  report  was  prepared  in  cooperation  with  the  Agricultural 
Research  Service  of  the  U.  S.  Department  of  Agriculture. 

The  list  of  chapters  (published  separately   only)    and   title 
for  each  chapter  are  as  follows: 

Chapter  I — Wheal  Producers  and  Wheat  Production 
II — Cotton  Producers  and  Cotton  Production 
III — Tobacco  and  Peanut  Producers  and  Production 
IV — Poultry  Producers  and  Poultry  Production 

V — Dairy  Producers  and  Dairy  Production 
VI — Western  Stock  Ranches  and  Livestock  Farms 
VII — Cash-Grain  and  Livestock  Producers  in  the  Corn 

Belt 
VIII— Part-Time  Farming 
IX — Agricultural    Producers    and    Production    in    the 
United  Stales — A  General  View 
Part  10. — Use  of  Fertilizer  and  Lime.    The  purpose  of  this  report 
is  to  present  in  one  publication  most  of  the  detailed  data  com- 
piled for  the  1954  Census  of  Agriculture  regarding  the  use  of 
fertilizer  and   lime.     The  report  presents   data  for   counties, 
State  economic  areas,   and  generalized  type-of-farming  areas 
regarding    the    quantity    used,    acreage    on    which    used,    and 
expenditures  for  fertilizer  and  lime.    The  Agricultural  Research 
Service  cooperated  with  the  Bureau  of  the  Census  in  the  prep- 
aration of  this  report. 
Part  11. — Farmers'  Expenditures.     This  report  presents  detailed 
data  on  expenditures  for  a  large  number  of  items  used  for  farm 
production  in    1955,   and  on  the  living  expenditures  of  farm 
operators'   families.      The   data   were   collected   and   compiled 
cooperatively  by  the  Agricultural    Marketing   Service    of   the 
U.  S.  Department  of  Agriculture  and  the  Bureau  of  the  Census. 
Part   12. — Methods  and   Procedures.     This  report  contains    an 
outline  and  a  description  of  the  methods  and  procedures  used 
in  taking  and  compiling  the  1954  Census  of  Agriculture. 


INTRODUCTION 


INTRODUCTION 


Purpose  and  scope. — American  agriculture  is  exceedingly  diverse 
and  is  undergoing  revolutionary  changes.  Farmers  and  their 
families  obtain  their  income  by  producing  a  large  variety  of 
products  under  a  large  variety  of  conditions  as  well  as  from  sources 
other  than  farming.  The  organization  of  production,  type  of 
farming,  productivity,  income,  expenditures,  size,  and  character- 
istics of  operators  of  the  4.8  million  farms  in  the  United  States 
vary  greatly.  Agriculture  has  been  a  dynamic,  moving,  adjusting 
part  of  our  economy.  Basic  changes  in  farming  have  been  occurring 
and  will  continue  to  be  necessary.  Adjustments  brought  by  tech- 
nological change,  by  changing  consumer  wants,  by  growth  of 
population,  and  by  changes  in  the  income  of  nonfarm  people,  have 
been  significant  forces  in  changing  agriculture  since  World  War  II. 
The  transition  from  war  to  an  approximate  peacetime  situation 
has  also  made  it  necessary  to  reduce  the  output  of  some  farm 
products.  Some  of  the  adjustments  in  agriculture  have  not  pre- 
sented relatively  difficult  problems  as  they  could  be  made  by  the 
transfer  of  resources  from  the  production  of  one  product  to  another. 
Others  require  substantial  shifts  in  resources  and  production. 

Moreover,  a  considerable  number  of  farm  families,  many  of  whom 
are  employed  full  time  in  agriculture,  have  relatively  low  incomes. 
Most  of  these  families  operate  farms  that  are  small  when  compared 
with  farms  that  produce  higher  incomes.  The  acreage  of  land  and 
the  amount  of  capital  controlled  by  the  operators  of  these  small 
farms  are  too  small  to  provide  a  very  high  level  of  income.  In 
recent  years,  many  farm  families  on  these  small  farms  have  made 
adjustments  by  leaving  the  farm  to  earn  their  incomes  elsewhere, 
by  discontinuing  their  farm  operations,  and  by  earning  more  non- 
farm  income  while  remaining  on  the  farm  or  on  the  place  they 
farmed  formerly. 

One  objective  of  this  report  is  to  describe  and  analyze  some  of 
the  existing  differences  and  recent  adjustments  in  the  major  types 
of  farming  and  farm  production.  For  important  commodities  and 
groups  of  farms,  the  report  aims  to  make  available,  largely  from 
the  detailed  data  for  the  1954  Census  of  Agriculture  but  in  a  more 
concise  form,  facts  regarding  the  size  of  farms,  capital,  labor,  and 
land  resources  on  farms,  amounts  and  sources  of  farm  income  and 
expenditures,  combinations  of  crop  and  livestock  enterprises, 
adjustment  problems,  operator  characteristics,  and  variation  in  use 
of  resources  and  in  size  of  farms  by  areas  and  for  widely  differing 
production  conditions.  Those  types  of  farms  on  which  production 
of  surplus  products  is  important  have  been  emphasized.  The 
report  will  provide  a  factual  basis  for  a  better  understanding  of 
the  widespread  differences  among  farms  in  regard  to  size,  resources, 
and  income.  It  will  also  provide  a  basis  for  evaluating  the  effects 
of  existing  and  proposed  farm  programs  on  the  production  and 
incomes  of  major  types  and  classes  of  farms. 

Income  from  nonfarm  sources  is  important  on  a  large  number 
of  farms.  About  1.4  million  of  the  4.8  million  farm-operator 
families,  or  about  3  in  10,  obtain  more  income  from  off-farm  sources 
than  from  the  sale  of  agricultural  products.  More  than  three- 
fourths  of  a  million  farm  operators  live  on  small-scale  part-time 
farms  and  ordinarily  are  not  dependent  on  farming  as  the  main 
source  of  family  income.  These  part-time  farmers  have  a  quite 
different  relation  to  adjustments,  changes,  and  farm  problems 
than  do  commercial  farmers.  A  description  of  and  facts  regarding 
these  part-time  farms  and  the  importance  of  nonfarm  income  for 
commercial  farms  are  presented  in  Chapter  8. 


Except  for  Chapter  8,  this  report  deals  with  commercial  farms 
(see  economic  class  of  farm) .  The  analysis  is  limited  to  the  major 
types  of  agricultural  production  and  deals  primarily  with  geo- 
graphic areas  in  which  each  of  the  major  types  of  agricultural 
production  has  substantial  significance. 

Source  of  data. — Most  of  the  data  presented  in  this  report  are 
from  special  compilations  made  for  the  1954  Census  of  Agriculture, 
although  pertinent  data  from  research  findings  and  surveys  of  the 
U.  S.  Department  of  Agriculture,  State  Agricultural  Colleges,  and 
other  agencies  have  been  used  to  supplement  Census  data.  The 
detailed  Census  data  used  for  this  report  are  contained  in  Part  8  of 
Volume  III  of  the  reports  of  the  1954  Census  of  Agriculture. 
Reference  should  be  made  to  that  report  for  detailed  explanations 
and  definitions  and  statements  regarding  the  characteristics  and 
reliability  of  the  data. 

Areas  for  which  data  are  presented. — Data  are  presented  in 
this  report  primarily  for  selected  economic  subregions  and  for  the 
United  States.  The  boundaries  of  the  119  subregions  used  for  the 
compilation  of  data  on  winch  this  report  is  based  are  indicated  by 
the  map  on  page  vi.  These  subregions  represent  primarily  general 
type-of-farming  areas.  Many  of  them  extend  into  two  or  more 
States.  (For  a  more  detailed  description  of  economic  subregions, 
see  the  publication  "Economic  Subregions  of  the  United  States, 
Series  Census  BAE;  No.  19,  published  cooperatively  by  the  Bureau 
of  the  Census,  and  the  Bureau  of  Agricultural  Economics,  U.  S. 
Department  of  Agriculture,  July  1953.) 

DEFINITIONS  AND  EXPLANATIONS 

Definitions  and  explanations  are  given  only  for  some  of  the  more 
important  items.  For  more  detailed  definitions  and  explanations, 
reference  can  be  made  to  Part  8  of  Volume  III  and  to  Volume  II  of 
the  reports  of  the  1954  Census  of  Agriculture. 

A  farm. — For  the  1954  Census  of  Agriculture,  places  of  3  or 
more  acres  were  counted  as  farms  if  the  annual  value  of  agricultural 
products,  exclusive  of  home-garden  products,  amounted  to  $150 
or  more.  The  agricultural  products  could  have  been  either  for 
home  use  or  for  sale.  Places  of  less  than  3  acres  were  counted  as 
farms  only  if  the  annual  value  of  sales  of  agricultural  products 
amounted  to  $150  or  more.  Places  for  which  the  value  of  agricul- 
tural products  for  1954  was  less  than  these  minima  because  of  crop 
failure  or  other  unusual  conditions,  and  places  operated  at  the  time 
of  the  Census  for  the  first  time  were  counted  as  farms  if  normally 
they  could  be  expected  to  produce  these  minimum  quantities  of 
agricultural  products. 

All  the  land  under  the  control  of  one  person  or  partnership  was 
included  as  one  farm.  Control  may  have  been  through  ownership, 
or  through  lease,  rental,  or  cropping  arrangement. 

Farm  operator. — A  "farm  operator"  is  a  person  who  operates 
a  farm,  either  performing  the  labor  himself  or  directly  supervising 
it.  He  may  be  an  owner,  a  hired  manager,  or  a  tenant,  renter,  or 
sharecropper.  If  he  rents  land  to  others  or  has  land  cropped  for 
him  by  others,  he  is  listed  as  the  operator  of  only  that  land  which 
he  retains.  In  the  case  of  a  partnership,  only  one  partner  was 
included  as  the  operator.  The  number  of  farm  operators  is  con- 
sidered the  same  as  the  number  of  farms. 


VIII 


FARMERS  AND  FARM  PRODUCTION 


Farms  reporting  or  operators  reporting. — Figures  for  farms 
reporting  or  operators  reporting,  based  on  a  tabulation  of  all  farms, 
represent  the  number  of  farms,  or  farm  operators,  for  which  the 
specified  item  was  reported.  For  example,  if  there  were  11,922 
farms  in  a  subregion  and  only  11,465  had  chickens  over  4  months 
old  on  hand,  the  number  of  farms  reporting  chickens  would  be 
11,465.  The  difference  between  the  total  number  of  farms  and  the 
number  of  farms  reporting  an  item  represents  the  number  of  farms 
not  having  that  item,  provided  the  inquiry  was  answered 
completely  for  all  farms. 

Farms  by  type. — The  classification  of  commercial  farms  by 
type  was  made  on  the  basis  of  the  relationship  of  the  value  of 
sales  from  a  particular  source,  or  sources,  to  the  total  value  of  all 
farm  products  sold  from  the  farm.  In  some  cases,  the  type  of 
farm  was  determined  on  the  basis  of  the  sale  of  an  individual  farm 
product,  such  as  cotton,  or  on  the  basis  of  the  sales  of  closely  re- 
lated products,  such  as  dairy  products.  In  other  cases,  the  type 
of  farm  was  determined  on  the  basis  of  sales  of  a  broader  group  of 
products,  such  as  grain  crops  including  corn,  sorghums,  all  small 
grains,  field  peas,  field  beans,  cowpeas,  and  soybeans.  In  order  to 
be  classified  as  a  particular  type,  sales  or  anticipated  sales  of  a 
product  or  group  of  products  had  to  represent  50  percent  or  more 
of  the  total  value  of  products  sold. 

The  types  of  commercial  farms  for  w-hich  data  are  shown,  to- 
gether with  the  product  or  group  of  products  on  which  the  classi- 
fication is  based  are: 

Product  or  group  of  products  amount- 
ing to  50  percent  or  more  of  the 
Type  of  farm  value  of  all  farm  products  sold 

Cash-grain Corn,   sorghum,   small   grains,  field 

peas,  field  beans,  cowpeas,  and 
soybeans. 

Cotton Cotton  (lint  and  seed). 

Other  field-crop Peanuts,  Irish  potatoes,  sweet- 
potatoes,  tobacco,  sugarcane,  sug- 
ar beets  for  sugar,  and  other 
miscellaneous  crops. 

Vegetable Vegetables. 

Fruit-and-nut Berries  and  other  small  fruits,  and 

tree  fruits,  nuts,  and  grapes. 

Dairv      Milk    and    other    dairy    products. 

The  criterion  of  50  percent  of  the 
total  sales  was  modified  in  the 
ease  of  dairy  farms.  A  farm  for 
which  the  value  of  sales  of  dairy 
products  represented  less  than  50 
percent  of  the  total  value  of  farm 
products  sold  was  classified  as  a 
dairy  farm  if — 

(a)  Milk  and  other  dairy  prod- 
ucts accounted  for  30 
percent  or  more  of  the 
total  value  of  products 
sold,  and 
(o)  Milk  cows  represented  50 
percent  or  more  of  all 
cows,  and 
(c)  Sales  of  dairy  products,  to- 
gether with  the  sales 
of  cattle  and  calves, 
amounted  to  50  percent 
or  more  of  the  total 
value   of   farm   products 


Poultry. 


Livestock  farms  other 
dairy  and  poultry. 


Chickens,  eggs,  turkeys,  and  other 

poultry  products. 
Cattle,   calves,  hogs,  sheep,  goats, 

wool,  and  mohair,   provided  the 

farm  did  not  qualify  as  a  dairy 

farm. 


Type  of  fa 


Product  or  group  of  products  amount- 
ing to  50  percent  or  more  of  the 
value  of  all  farm  products  sold 

Farms    were    classified   as    general 

when  the  value  of  products  from 
one  source  or  group  of  sources 
did  not  represent  as  much  as  50 
percent  of  the  total  value  of  all 
farm  products  sold.  Separate 
figures  are  given  for  three  kinds 
of  general  farms: 

(a)  Primarily  crop. 

(b)  Primarily  livestock. 

(c)  Crop  and  livestock. 
Primarily  crop  farms  are  those  for 

which  the  sale  of  one  of  the 
following  crops  or  groups  of 
crops — vegetables,  fruits  and 
nuts,  cotton,  cash  grains,  or  other 
field  crops — did  not  amount  to 
50  percent  or  more  of  the  value 
of  all  farm  products  sold,  but 
for  which  the  value  of  sales  for 
all  these  groups  of  crops  repre- 
sented 70  percent  or  more  of  the 
value  of  all  farm  products  sold. 
Primarily  livestock  farms  are  those 
which  could  not  qualify  as  dairy 
farms,  poultry  farms,  or  livestock 
farms  other  than  dairy  and 
poultry,  but  on  which  the  sale 
of  livestock  and  poultry  and 
livestock  and  poultry  products 
amounted  to  70  percent  or  more 
of  the  value  of  all  farm  products 
sold. 
General  crop  and  livestock  farms  are 
those  which  could  not  be  classi- 
fied as  either  crop  farms  or  live- 
stock farms,  but  on  which  the 
sale  of  all  crops  amounted  to  at 
least  30  percent  but  less  than  70 
percent  of  the  total  value  of  all 
farm  products  sold. 

This  group  of  farms  includes  those 

that  had  50  percent  or  more  of 
the  total  value  of  products  ac- 
counted for  by  sale  of  horticul- 
tural products,  or  sale  of  horses, 
or  sale  of  forest  products. 

Farms  by  economic  class. — A  classification  of  farms  by  eco- 
nomic class  was  made  for  the  purpose  of  segregating  groups  of 
farms  that  are  somewhat  alike  in  their  characteristics  and  size  of 
operation.  This  classification  was  made  in  order  to  present  an 
accurate  description  of  the  farms  in  each  class  and  in  order  to 
provide  basic  data  for  an  analysis  of  the  organization  of  agriculture. 

The  classification  of  farms  by  economic  class  was  made  on  the 
basis  of  three  factors;  namely,  total  value  of  all  farm  products 
sold,  number  of  days  the  farm  operator  worked  off  the  farm,  and 
the  relationship  of  the  income  received  from  nonfarm  sources  by 
the  operator  and  members  of  his  family  to  the  value  of  all  farm 
products  sold.  Farms  operated  by  institutions,  experiment  sta- 
tions, grazing  associations,  and  community  projects  were  classified 
as  abnormal,  regardless  of  any  of  the  three  factors. 

For  the  purpose  of  determining  the  code  for  economic  class  and 
type  of  farm,  it  was  necessary  to  obtain  the  total  value  of  farm 
products  sold  as  well  as  the  value  of  some  individual  products 
sold. 

The  total  value  of  farm  products  sold  was  obtained  by  adding 
the  reported  or  estimated  values  for  all  products  sold  from  the 
farm.  The  value  of  livestock,  livestock  products  except  wool  and 
mohair,  vegetables,  nursery  and  greenhouse  products,  and  forest 


Miscellaneous. 


INTRODUCTION 


IX 


products  was  obtained  by  the  enumerator  from  the  farm  operator 
for  each  farm.  The  enumerator  also  obtained  from  the  farm 
operator  the  quantity  sold  for  corn,  sorghums,  small  grains,  hays, 
and  small  fruits.  The  value  of  sales  for  these  crops  was  obtained 
by  multiplying  the  quantity  sold  by  State  average  prices. 

The  quantity  sold  was  estimated  for  all  other  farm  products. 
The  entire  quantity  produced  for  wool,  mohair,  cotton,  tobacco, 
sugar  beets  for  sugar,  sugarcane  for  sugar,  broomcorn,  hops,  and 
mint  for  oil  was  estimated  as  sold.  To  obtain  the  value  of  each 
product  sold,  the  quantity  sold  was  multiplied  by  State  average 
prices. 

In  making  the  classification  of  farms  by  economic  class,  farms 
were  grouped  into  two  major  groups,  namely,  commercial  farms 
and  other  farms.  In  general,  all  farms  with  a  value  of  sales  of 
farm  products  amounting  to  $1,200  or  more  were  classified  as 
commercial.  Farms  with  a  value  of  sales  of  $250  to  $1,199  were 
classified  as  commercial  only  if  the  farm  operator  worked  off  the 
farm  less  than  100  days  or  if  the  income  of  the  farm  operator  and 
members  of  his  family  received  from  nonfarm  sources  was  less  than 
the  total  value  of  all  farm  products  sold. 

Land  in  farms  according  to  use.— Land  in  farms  was  classified 
according  to  the  use  made  of  it  in  1954.  The  classes  of  land 
are  mutually  exclusive,  i.  e.,  each  acre  of  land  was  included  only 
once  even  though  it  may  have  had  more  than  one  use  during  the 
year. 

The  classes  referred  to  in  this  report  are  as  follows: 

Cropland  harvested. — This  includes  land  from  which  crops 
were  harvested;  land  from  which  hay  (including  wild  hay)  was 
cut;  and  land  in  small  fruits,  orchards,  vineyards,  nurseries,  and 
greenhouses.  Land  from  which  two  or  more  crops  were  reported 
as  harvested  was  to  be  counted  only  once. 

Cropland  used  only  for  pasture. — In  the  1954  Census,  the 
enumerator's  instructions  stated  that  rotation  pasture  and  all 
other  cropland  that  was  used  only  for  pasture  were  to  be  in- 
cluded under  this  class.  No  further  definition  of  cropland 
pastured  was  given  the  farm  operator  or  enumerator.  Per- 
manent open  pasture  may,  therefore,  have  been  included  under 
this  item  or  under  "other  pasture,"  depending  on  whether  the 
enumerator  or  farm  operator  considered  it  as  cropland. 

Cropland  not  harvested  and  not  pastured. — This  item  includes 
idle  cropland,  land  in  soil-improvement  crops  only,  land  on 
which  all  crops  failed,  land  seeded  to  crops  for  harvest  after 
1954,  and  cultivated  summer  fallow. 

In  the  Western  States,  this  class  was  subdivided  to  show 
separately  the  acres  of  cultivated  summer  fallow.  In  these 
States,  the  acreage  not  in  cultivated  summer  fallow  represents 
largely  crop  failure.  There  are  very  few  counties  in  the  West- 
ern States  in  which  there  is  a  large  acreage  of  idle  cropland  or 
in  which  the  growing  of  soil-improvement  crops  is  an  important 
use  of  the  land. 

In  the  States  other  than  the  Western  States,  this  general 
class  was  subdivided  to  show  separately  the  acres  of  idle  crop- 
land (not  used  for  crops  or  for  pasture  in'  1954) .  In  these  States, 
the  incidence  of  crop  failure  is  usually  low.  It  was  expected 
that  the  acreage  figure  that  excluded  idle  land  would  reflect 
the  acreage  in  soil-improvement  crops.  However,  the  1954 
crop  year  was  one  of  low  rainfall  in  many  Eastern  and  Southern 
States  and,  therefore,  in  these  areas  the  acreage  of  cropland  not 
harvested  and  not  pastured  includes  more  land  on  which  all 
crops  failed  than  would  usually  be  the  case. 

Cultivated  summer  fallow. — This  item  includes  cropland 
that  was  plowed  and  cultivated  but  left  unseeded  for  several 
months  to  control  weeds  and  conserve  moisture.  No  land 
from  which  crops  were  harvested  in  1954  was  to  be  included 
under  this  item. 

Cropland,  total. — This  includes  cropland  harvested,  cropland 
used  only  for  pasture,  and  cropland  not  harvested  and  not 
pastured. 

Land  pastured,  total. — This  includes  cropland  used  only  for 
pasture,  woodland  pastured,  and  other  pasture  (not  cropland 
and  not  woodland). 
423026—57 2 


Woodland,    total. — This    includes    woodland    pastured    and 

woodland  not  pastured. 

Value  of  land  and  buildings. — The  value  to  be  reported  was 
the  approximate  amount  for  which  the  land  and  the  buildings  on 
it  would  sell. 

Off-farm  work  and  other  income. — Many  farm  operators  receive 
a  part  of  their  income  from  sources  other  than  the  sale  of  farm 
products  from  their  farms.  The  1954  Agriculture  Questionnaire 
included  several  inquiries  relating  to  work  off  the  farm  and  non- 
farm  income.  These  inquiries  called  for  the  number  of  days 
worked  off  the  farm  by  the  farm  operator;  whether  other  members 
of  the  operator's  family  worked  off  the  farm;  and  whether  the 
farm  operator  received  income  from  other  sources,  such  as  sale 
of  products  from  land  rented  out,  cash  rent,  boarders,  old  age 
assistance,  pensions,  veterans'  allowances,  unemployment  com- 
pensation, interest,  dividends,  profits  from  nonfarm  business, 
and  help  from  other  members  of  the  operator's  family.  Another 
inquiry  asked  whether  the  income  of  the  operator  and  his  family 
from  off-farm  work  and  other  sources  was  greater  than  the  total 
value  of  all  agricultural  products  sold  from  the  farm  in  1954. 
Off-farm  work  was  to  include  work  at  nonfarm  jobs,  businesses, 
or  professions,  whether  performed  on  the  farm  premises  or  else- 
where; also,  work  on  someone  else's  farm  for  pay  or  wages.  Ex- 
change work  was  not  to  be  included. 

Specified  facilities  and  equipment. — Inquiries  were  made  in 
1954  to  determine  the  presence  or  absence  of  selected  items  on 
each  place  such  as  (1)  telephone,  (2)  piped  running  water,  (3) 
electricity,  (4)  television  set,  (5)  home  freezer,  (6)  electric  pig 
brooder,  (7)  milking  machine,  and  (8)  power  feed  grinder.  Such 
facilities  or  equipment  were  to  be  counted  even  though  tem- 
porarily out  of  order.  Piped  running  water  was  defined  as  water 
piped  from  a  pressure  system  or  by  gravity  flow  from  a  natural 
or  artificial  source.  The  enumerator's  instructions  stated  that 
pig  brooders  were  to  include  those  heated  by  an  electric  heating 
element,  by  an  infrared  or  heat  bulb,  or  by  ordinary  electric  bulbs. 
They  could  be  homemade. 

The  number  of  selected  types  of  other  farm  equipment  was  also 
obtained  for  a  sample  of  farms.  The  selected  kinds  of  farm 
equipment  to  be  reported  were  (1)  grain  combines  (for  harvesting 
and  threshing  grains  or  seeds  in  one  operation) ;  (2)  cornpickers ; 
(3)  pickup  balers  (stationary  ones  not  to  be  reported) ;  (4)  field 
forage  harvesters  (for  field  chopping  of  silage  and  forage  crops) ; 
(5)  motortrucks;  (6)  wheel  tractors  (other  than  garden);  (7) 
garden  tractors;  (8)  crawler  tractors  (tracklaying,  caterpillar) ; 
(9)  automobiles;  and  (10)  artificial  ponds,  reservoirs,  and  earth 
tanks. 

Wheel  tractors  were  to  include  homemade  tractors  but  were  not 
to  include  implements  having  built-in  power  units  such  as  self- 
propelled  combines,  powered  buck  rakes,  etc.  Pickup  and  truck- 
trailer  combinations  were  to  be  reported  as  motortrucks.  School 
buses  were  not  to  be  reported,  and  jeeps  and  station  wagons  were 
to  be  included  as  motortrucks  or  automobiles,  depending  on 
whether  used  for  hauling  farm  products  or  supplies,  or  as  passenger 
vehicles. 

Farm  labor. — The  farm-labor  inquiries  for  1954,  called  for  the 
number  of  persons  doing  farmwork  or  chores  on  the  place  during 
a  specified  calendar  week.  Since  starting  dates  of  the  1954  enumer- 
ation varied  by  areas  or  States,  the  calendar  week  to  which  the 
farm-labor  inquiries  related  varied  also.  The  calendar  week  was 
September  26-October  2  or  October  24-30.  States  with  the 
September  26-October  2  calendar  week  were:  Arizona,  California, 
Colorado,  Connecticut,  Florida,  Idaho,  Kansas,  Kentucky, 
Louisiana,  Maine,  Massachusetts,  Michigan,  Minnesota,  Montana, 
Nebraska,  Nevada,  New  Hampshire,  New  Jersey,  New   Mexico, 


FARMERS  AND  FARM  PRODUCTION 


New  York,  North  Dakota,  Oklahoma,  Oregon,  Pennsylvania, 
Rhode  Island,  South  Dakota,  Tennessee,  Texas,  Utah,  Vermont, 
Washington,  Wisconsin,  and  Wyoming.  States  with  the  October 
24-30  calendar  week  were :  Alabama,  Arkansas,  Delaware,  Georgia, 
Illinois,  Indiana,  Iowa,  Maryland,  Mississippi,  Missouri,  North 
Carolina,  Ohio,  South  Carolina,  Virginia,  and  West  Virginia. 
Farmwork  was  to  include  any  work,  chores,  or  planning  necessary 
to  the  operation  of  the  farm  or  ranch  business.  Housework, 
contract  construction  work,  and  labor  involved  when  equipment 
was  hired  (custom  work)  were  not  to  be  included. 

The  farm-labor  information  was  obtained  in  three  parts: 
(1)  Operators  working,  (2)  unpaid  members  of  the  operator's  family 
working,  and  (3)  hired  persons  working.  Operators  were  consid- 
ered as  working  if  they  worked  1  or  more  hours;  unpaid  members 
of  the  operator's  family,  if  they  worked  15  or  more  hours;  and 
hired  persons,  if  they  worked  any  time  during  the  calendar  week 
specified.  Instructions  contained  no  specifications  regarding  age 
of  the  persons  working. 

Regular  and  seasonal  workers.- — Hired  persons  working  on 
the  farm  during  the  specified  week  were  classed  as  "regular" 
workers  if  the  period  of  actual  or  expected  employment  was  150 
days  or  more  during  the  year,  and  as  "seasonal"  workers  if  the 
period  of  actual  or  expected  employment  was  less  than  150  days. 
If  the  period  of  expected  employment  was  not  reported,  the 
period  of  employment  was  estimated  for  the  individual  farm 
after  taking  into  account  such  items  as  the  basis  of  payment, 
wage  rate,  expenditures  for  labor  in  1954,  and  the  type  and 
other  characteristics  of  the  farm. 

Specified  farm  expenditures. — The  1954  Census  obtained  data 
for  selected  farm  expense  items  in  addition  to  those  for  fertilizer 
and  lime.  The  expenditures  were  to  include  the  total  specified 
expenditures  for  the  place  whether  made  by  landlord,  tenant,  or 
both. 

Expenditures  for  machine  hire  were  to  include  any  labor  in- 
cluded in  the  cost  of  such  machine  hire.  Machine  hire  refers  to 
custom  machine  work  such  as  tractor  hire,  threshing,  combining, 
silo  filling,  baling,  ginning,  plowing,  and  spraying.  If  part  of  the 
farm  products  was  given  as  pay  for  machine  hire,  the  value  of  the 
products  traded  for  this  service  was  to  be  included  in  the  amount 
of  expenditures  reported.  The  cost  of  trucking,  freight,  and 
express  was  not  to  be  included. 

Expenditures  for  hired  labor  were  to  include  only  cash  pay- 
ments. Expenditures  for  housework,  custom  work,  and  contract 
construction  work  were  not  to  be  included. 

Expenditures  for  feed  were  to  include  the  expenditures  for 
pasture,  salt,  condiments,  concentrates,  and  mineral  supplements, 
as  well  as  those  for  grain,  hay,  and  mill  feeds.  Expenditures  for 
grinding  and  mixing  feeds  were  also  to  be  included.  Payments 
made  by  a  tenant  to  his  landlord  for  feed  grown  on  the  land  rented 
by  the  tenant  were  not  to  be  included. 

Expenditures  for  gasoline  and  other  petroleum  fuel  and  oil  were 
to  include  only  those  used  for  the  farm  business.  Petroleum 
products  used  for  the  farmer's  automobile  for  pleasure  or  used 
exclusively  in  the  farm  home  for  heating,  cooking,  and  lighting 
were  not  to  be  included. 

Crops  harvested. — The  information  on  crops  harvested  refers 
to  the  acreage  and  quantity  harvested  for  the  1954  crop  year.  An 
exception  was  made  for  land  in  fruit  orchards  and  planted  nut 
trees.  In  this  case,  the  acreage  represents  that  in  both  bearing 
and  nonbearing  trees  and  vines  as  of  October  and  November  1954. 

Hay. — The  data  for  hay  includes  all  kinds  of  hay  except  soy- 
bean, cowpea,  sorghum,  and  peanut  hay. 

Livestock  and  poultry. — The  data  on  the  number  of  livestock 
and  poultry  represent  the  number  on  hand  on  the  day  of  enumera- 


tion (October-November  1954).  The  data  relating  to  livestock 
products  and  the  number  of  livestock  sold  relate  to  the  sales  made 
during  the  calendar  year  1954. 

LABOR  RESOURCES 

The  data  for  labor  resources  available  represent  estimates  based 
largely  on  Census  data  and  developed  for  the  purpose  of  making 
comparisons  among  farms  of  various  size  of  operations.  The 
labor  resources  available  are  stated  in  terms  of  man-equivalents. 
To  obtain  the  man-equivalents  the  total  number  of  farm  opera- 
tors as  reported  by  the  1954  Census  were  adjusted  for  estimated 
man-years  of  work  off  the  farm  and  for  the  number  of  farm  opera- 
tors 65  years  old  and  over.  The  farm  operator  was  taken  to  rep- 
resent a  full  man-equivalent  of  labor  unless  he  was  65  years  or 
older  or  unless  he  worked  at  an  off-farm  job  in  1954. 

The  man-equivalent  estimated  for  farm  operators  reporting  spec- 
ified amounts  of  off-farm  work  were  as  follows: 

Estimated 
Days  worked  off  the  farm  in  1954  man-equivalent 

1-99  days 0.85 

100-199  days .  50 

200  days  and  over .  15 

The  man-equivalent  for  farm  operators  65  years  of  age  and  older 
was  estimated  at  0.5. 

Man-equivalents  of  members  of  the  farm  operator's  family  were 
based  upon  Census  data  obtained  in  response  to  the  question 
"How  many  members  of  your  family  did  15  or  more  hours  of  farm 
work  on  this  place  the  week  of  September  26-October  2  (or,  in 
some  areas,  the  week  of  October  24-30)  without  receiving  cash 
wages?"  Each  family  worker  was  considered  as  0.5  man-equiva- 
lent. This  estimate  provides  allowance  for  the  somewhat  higher 
incidence  of  women,  children,  and  elderly  persons  in  the  unpaid 
family  labor  force. 

In  addition,  the  number  of  unpaid  family  workers  who  were 
reported  as  working  15  or  more  hours  in  the  week  of  September 
26-October  2  was  adjusted  to  take  account  of  seasonal  changes  in 
farm  employment.  Using  published  and  unpublished  findings  of 
the  U.  S.  Department  of  Agriculture  and  State  Agricultural  Col- 
leges, and  depending  largely  upon  knowledge  and  experience  with 
the  geographic  areas  and  type  of  farming,  each  author  deter- 
mined the  adjustment  factor  needed  to  correct  the  number  of 
family  workers  reported  for  the  week  of  September  26-October  2 
to  an  annual  average  basis. 

Man-equivalents  of  hired  workers  are  based  entirely  upon  the 
expenditure  for  cash  wages  and  the  average  wage  of  permanent 
hired  laborers  as  reported  in  the  1954  Census  of  Agriculture. 

Value  of  or  investment  in  livestock. — Numbers  of  specified 
livestock  and  poultry  in  each  subregion  were  multiplied  by  a 
weighted  average  value  per  head.  The  average  values  were  com- 
puted from  data  compiled  for  each  kind  of  livestock  for  the  1954 
Census  of  Agriculture.  The  total  value  does  not  include  the  value 
of  goats.  (For  a  description  of  the  method  of  obtaining  the  value 
of  livestock,  see  Chapter  VI  of  Volume  II  of  the  reports  for  the 
1954  Census  of  Agriculture.) 

Value  of  investment  in  machinery  and  equipment. — The  data 
on  value  of  investment  in  machinery  and  equipment  were  developed 
for  the  purpose  of  making  broad  comparisons  among  types  and 
economic  classes  of  farms  and  by  subregions.  Numbers  of  specified 
machines  on  farms,  as  reported  by  the  Census,  were  multiplied  by 
estimated  average  value  per  machine.  Then  the  total  values  ob- 
tained were  adjusted  upward  to  provide  for  the  inclusion  of  items 
of  equipment  not  included  in  the  Census  inventory  of  farm 
machinery. 


INTRODUCTION 


M 


The  estimates  for  average  value  of  specified  machines  and  the 
proportion  of  total  value  of  all  machinery  represented  by  the 
value  of  these  machines  were  based  largely  on  published  and  un- 
published data  from  the  "Farm  Costs  and  Returns"  surveys  con- 
ducted currently  by  the  Agricultural  Research  Service,  U.  S. 
Department  of  Agriculture.1  Modifications  were  made  as  needed 
in  the  individual  chapters  on  the  basis  of  State  and  local  studies. 
The  total  estimated  value  of  all  machinery  for  all  types  and 
economic  classes  of  farms  is  approximately  equal  to  the  value  of 
all  machinery  as  estimated  by  the  U.  S.  Department  of  Agriculture. 

Value  of  farm  products  sold,  or  gross  sales. — Data  on  the 
value  of  the  various  farm  products  sold  were  obtained  for  1954  by 
two  methods.  First,  the  values  of  livestock  and  livestock  prod- 
ucts sold,  except  wool  and  mohair;  vegetables  harvested  for  sale; 
nursery  and  greenhouse  products;  and  forest  products  were 
obtained  by  asking  each  farm  operator  the  value  of  sales.  Second, 
the  values  of  all  other  farm  products  sold  were  computed.  For  the 
most  important  crops,  the  quantity  sold  or  to  be  sold  was  obtained 
for  each  farm.  The  entire  quantity  harvested  for  cotton  and 
cottonseed,  tobacco,  sugar  beets  for  sugar,  hops,  mint  for  oil,  and 
sugarcane  for  sugar  was  considered  sold.  The  quantity  of  minor 
crops  sold  was  estimated.  The  value  of  sales  for  each  crop  was 
computed  by  multiplying  the  quantity  sold  by  State  average 
prices.  In  the  case  of  wool  and  mohair,  the  value  of  sales  was 
computed  by  multiplying  the  quantity  shorn  or  clipped  by  the 
State  average  prices. 

Gross  sales  include  the  value  of  all  kinds  of  farm  products  sold. 
The  total  does  not  include  rental  and  benefit,  soil  conservation, 
price  adjustment,  Sugar  Act,  and  similar  payments.     The  totsl 


does  include  the  value  of  the  landlord's  share  of  a  crop  removed 
from  a  farm  operated  by  a  share  tenant.  In  most  of  the  tables, 
detailed  data  are  presented  for  only  the  more  important  sources 
of  gross  sales  and  the  total  for  the  individual  farm  products 
or  sources  will  not  equal  the  total  as  the  values  for  the  less  impor- 
tant sources  or  farm  products  have  been  omitted.  (For  a  detailed 
statement  regarding  the  reliability  and  method  of  obtaining  the 
value  of  farm  products  sold,  reference  should  be  made  to  Chapter 
IX  of  Volume  II  of  the  reports  for  the  1954  Census  of  Agriculture.) 

Livestock  and  livestock  products  sold. — The  value  of  sales  for 
livestock  and  livestock  products  includes  the  value  of  live  animals 
sold,  dairy  products  sold,  poultry  and  poultry  products  sold,  and 
the  calculated  value  of  wool  and  mohair.  The  value  of  bees, 
honey,  fur  animals,  goats,  and  goat  milk  is  not  included. 

The  value  of  dairy  products  includes  the  value  of  whole  milk  and 
cream  sold,  but  does  not  include  the  value  of  butter  and  cheese, 
made  on  the  farm,  and  sold.  The  value  of  poultry  and  products 
includes  the  value  of  chickens,  broilers,  chicken  eggs,  turkeys, 
turkey  eggs,  ducks,  geese,  and  other  miscellaneous  poultry  and 
poultry  products  sold.  The  value  does  not  include  the  value 
of  baby  chicks  sold. 

Crops  sold. — Vegetables  sold  includes  the  value  of  all  vegetables 
harvested  for  sale,  but  does  not  include  the  value  of  Irish  potatoes 
and  sweetpotatoes. 

The  value  of  all  crops  sold  includes  the  value  of  all  crops  sold 
except  forest  products.  The  value  of  field  crops  sold  includes  the 
value  of  sales  of  all  crops  sold  except  vegetables,  small  fruits  and 
berries,  fruits,  and  nuts. 


i  Farm  Costs  am]  Return-;,  ia.'i5  (with  comparisons*,  Aericulture  Information  Bulletin  No.  1SK,  Agricultural  Research  Service,  U.  S.  Department  of  Agriculture,  June  1958. 


CHAPTER  IX 

AGRICULTURAL  PRODUCERS  AND  PRODUCTION  IN  THE 
UNITED  STATES— A  GENERAL  VIEW 


(i) 


CONTENTS 


Page 

Major  sectors  in  agriculture 7 

Economic  classification  of  farms 9 

Commercial  and  noncommercial  farms 9 

Part-time  and  residential  farms 9 

Commercial  farms 10 

Economic  classes  of  commercial  farms 10 

Economic  class  as  a  measure  of  farm  size 10 

Geographic  distribution  of  economic  classes.  11 
Characteristics  and   limitations   of  the   eco- 
nomic classification 12 

Types  of  commercial  farms 12 

A  measure  of  commodity  specialization 13 

Geographic  distribution  of  types  of  farms 13 

Cash-grain  farms 13 

Cotton  farms 13 

Other  field-crop  farms 13 

Vegetable  farms 14 

Fruit-and-nut  farms 14 

Dairy  farms 14 

Poultry  farms 15 

Livestock  farms  other  than  dairy  and  poul- 
try   15 

General  farms 15 

Miscellaneous  farms 16 

Type-of-farming  areas 16 

Type  of  farm  by  economic  class 17 

Changes  in  the  structure  of  commercial  farming 18 

Changes  affect  farmers  differently 18 

Changes  by  economic  classes 18 

Specialization  in  farming 19 

Changes  in  type  of  farm 20 

Changes  in  type  by  economic  class 20 

Geographic  changes  in  type  and  economic  class  _ .  21 

Changes  in  size  of  acreage 24 

Change  in  acreage  by  economic  class 25 

Change  in  acreage  by  type  of  farm 26 

Changes  in  farm  operator  characteristics 26 

Age  of  operator 26 

Tenure  of  operator 27 

Off-farm  work  and  other  income 27 

Residence  of  farm  operator 27 

Changes  in  farm  resources 28 

Tractors  on  farms 28 

Land  resources  and  market  output 28 


Page 

Characteristics  of  type  of  farm  by  economic  class 29 

Farm  operator  characteristics 29 

Color  and  tenure  of  operator 29 

Residence  of  farm  operators 30 

Work  off  the  farm  and  other  income 30 

Age  of  operator 30 

Man-equivalents  of  labor  used 31 

Operator  labor 31 

Unpaid  family  labor 31 

Hired  labor 32 

Cash  wages  paid 32 

Class  of  work  power 34 

Land  in  farms 34 

Cropland  harvested 37 

Value  of  land  and  buildings 38 

Value  of  livestock 40 

Estimated  value  of  machinery 40 

Total  value  of  investment 41 

Value  of  farm  products  sold 42 

Gross  sales  per  acre 43 

Yield  of  corn  per  acre  harvested 43 

Gross  sales  per  $100  of  capital  investment 43 

Gross  sales  per  man-equivalent 44 

Limitations  of  relating  sales  to  resources 44 

Investment  per  man-equivalent 44 

Total  farm  expenses 45 

Cash  wages 46 

Machine  hire 47 

Purchase  of  livestock  and  poultry 47 

Feed  for  livestock  and  poultry 47 

Seeds,  plants,  and  trees 47 

Commercial  fertilizer  and  liming  materials..  47 
Fuel,  repairs,  and  other  operating  costs  for 

motor  vehicles  and  farm  machinery 48 

Marketing  cost 48 

Miscellaneous  farm  operating  expenses 48 

Property  taxes  and  interest 48 

Capital  expenditures 48 

Total  motor  vehicle  and  machinery  expenses 48 

Census  specified  expenses 49 

Relation    of  Census  specified    expenses  to   total 

farm   expenses 49 

Estimated  value  added 50 

Value  added  per  man-equivalent 51 

Value  added  per  $1,000  of  capital  investment.  51 

Home  facilities. 52 

Electricity 52 

Index  of  home  facilities 52 

3 


CONTENTS 
MAPS  AND  CHARTS 


Farm  labor  productivity 

Population:  Total,  non-farm,    and    farm,   United    States, 

1910  to  1954 

Number  of  farm  operators  working  off  their  farms  by  num- 
ber of  days  worked,  for  the  United  States  and  areas, 

1930-1954 

Farm  income  and  population 

United  States  farms 

Part-time  farms,  number,  1954 

Residential  farms,  number,  1954 

Commercial  farms,  number,  1954 

Economic  Class  I  farms,  number,  1954 

Economic  Class  II  farms,  number,  1954 

Economic  Class  III  farms,  number,  1954 

Economic  Class  IV  farms,  number,  1954 

Economic  Class  V  farms,  number,  1954 

Economic  Class  VI  farms,  number,  1954 

Cash-grain  farms,  number,  1954 

Cotton  farms,  number,  1954 

Other  field-crop  farms,  number,  1954 

Vegetable  farms,  number,  1954 

Fruit-and-nut  farms,  number,  1 954 

Dairy  farms,  number,  1954 

Poultry  farms,  number,  1954 

Livestock  farms,  number,  1954 

General  farms,  number,  1954 


Page 

7 


Type-of-farming  areas,  based  on  type  accounting  for  50 
percent  or  more  of  commercial  farms,  1954 

Cash-grain     farms — increase    and    decrease    in     number, 
1950-1954 

Cotton  farms — increase  and  decrease  in  number,  1950-1954. 

Other  field-crop  farms — increase  and  decrease  in  number, 
1950-1954 .. 

Vegetable     farms — increase     and     decrease     in.    number, 
1950-1954 ... —  . I 

Fruit-and-nut   farms — increase   and   decrease   in   number, 
1950-1954 

Dairy  farms — increase  and  decrease  in  number,  1950-1954. 

Poultry  farms — increase  and  decrease  in  number,  1950-1954. 

Livestockfarms — increase  and  decrease  in  number,  1950-1954. 

General  farms — -increase  and  decrease  in  number,  1950-1954. 

Economic  Class  I  farms — increase  and  decrease  in  number, 
1950-1954 ... 

Economic  Class  II  farms — increase  and  decrease  in  num- 
ber, 1950-1954 

Economic  Class  III  farms — increase  and  decrease  in  num- 
ber, 1950-1954 

Economic  Class  IV  farms — increase  and  decrease  in  num- 
ber, 1950-1954 

Economic  Class  V  farms — increase  and  decrease  in  number, 
1950-1954 

Economic  Class  VI  farms — increase  and 
ber,  1950-1954 


TABLES 


Table— 

1. — Farms  and  specified  farm  resources  by  economic  class  of  commercial  farm,  for  the  United  States:  1954 

2, — Number  of  farms  in  each  type  of  farm  by  economic  class,  for  the  United  States:   1954 

3. — Percent  distribution  of  farms  in  each  type  of  farm  by  economic  class,  for  the  United  States:  1954 

4. — Percent  distribution  of  farms  in  each  economic  class,  by  type  of  farm,  for  the  United  States:  1954 

5. — Changes  in  number  and  percent  distribution  of  commercial  farms,  by  economic  class,  for  the  United  States:  1950  to  1954... 
6. — Number  and  proportion  of  farms  having  production  or  sales  of  specified  commodities,  for  the  United  States  by  specified 

years:  1929  to  1954 

7. — Changes  in  number  and  percent  distribution  of  commercial  farms,  by  type  of  farm,  for  the  United  States:  1950  to  1954 

8. — Change  in  number  of  farms,  for  each  type  of  commercial  farm,  by  economic  class,  for  the  United  States:   1950  to  1954 ... 

9. — Changes  in  number  of  farms  by  size  and  percent  distribution  of  commercial  farms  by  size,  for  the  United  States:   1950 


Page 

16 

22 
22 

22 

22 

22 
22 
23 
23 
23 

24 

24 

24 

24 

24 

24 


Page 
11 

17 
17 
17 


to  1954. 


10. — Number  and  percent  distribution  of  farms,  1954,  and  change  in  number  of  farms,  1950  to  1954;  by  size  and  economic  class, 
for  the  United  States 

11.  Number  and  percent  distribution,  1954,  and  change  in  number  of  farms,  1950  to  1954;  by  size  and  type  of  farm,  for  the  United 
States 

12. — Specified  farms  and  farm-operator  characteristics,  by  type  and  by  economic  class  for  commercial  farms,  for  the  United  States: 
1950  and  1954 

13.— Specified  farm  resources,  percent  1954  is  of  1950,  by  economic  class  and  by  type  of  farm,  for  the  United  States .. 

14. — Proportion  of  farms  operated  by  owners,  part-owners,  and  managers,  and  croppers,  and  by  white  and  nonwhite  operators, 

for  each  type  of  farm  by  economic  class,  for  the  United  States:  1954 

15. — Percent  distribution  of  farms  in  each  tenure  and  color  group  by  type  and  economic  class  of  farm,  for  the  United  States:   1954. 

16. — Percent  of  nonresident  operators  for  type  of  farm  by  economic  class,  for  the  United  States:  1954 

17. — Operators  working  off  the  farm  100  or  more  days  as  percentage  of  operators  reporting  as  to  off -farm  work,  for  each  type  of 

farm,  by  economic  class,  for  the  United  States:  1954 

18. — Percentage  of  farms  with  other  income  greater  than  the  value  of  farm  products  sold,  for  each  type  of  farm,  by  economic  class, 

for  the  United  States:  1954 

19. — Median  age  of  operator  for  type  of  farm  by  economic  class,  for  the  United  States:  1954 

20. — Average  man-equivalents  of  labor  used  on  each  type  of  farm  by  economic  class,  for  the  United  States:  1954 

21. — Percentage  of  farms  reporting  $5,000  or  more  cash  wages  paid,  for  each  type  of  commercial  farm,  by  economic  class,  for  the 

United  States:  1954. -.— 

22. — Percentage  distribution  of  commercial  farms  in  each  type,  by  economic  class  of  farm,  by  amount  of  expenditure  for  hired 

labor,  for  the  United  States:  1954 

23. — Class  of  work  power:  Percentage  distribution  of  farms  by  type  and  by  specified  economic  classes,  for  the  United  States:  1954.. 

24. — Percent  distribution  of  total  land  for  each  economic  class,  by  type  of  farm,  for  the  United  States:  1954 

25. — Percent  distribution  of  total  land  in  farms  for  each  type  of  commercial  farm,  by  economic  class,  for  the  United  States:  1954.. 
26. — Average  size  of  farm  for  each  type  of  commercial  farm,  by  economic  class,  for  the  United  States:  1954 


CONTENTS  5 

TABLES— Continued 

Table—  l'"0t 

27. — Number  of  farms  in  specified  acreage-size  groups  for  each  type  of  commercial  farm,  by  economic  class,  for  the  United  States: 

1954 36 

28. — Cropland  harvested  as  a  percent  of  total  land  in  farms  for  each  type  of  farm,  by  economic  class  of  farm,  for  the  United  States: 

1954 1 37 

29. — Percent  distribution  of  total  acreage  of  cropland  harvested  for  each  type  of  commercial  farm  by  economic  class,  for  the  United 

States:  1954 37 

30. — Percent  distribution  of  total  acreage  of  cropland  harvested  for  each  economic  class,  by  type  of  farm,  for  the  United  States: 

1954 37 

31. — Average  acreage  of  cropland  harvested  per  farm  for  each  type  of  commercial  farm,  by  economic  class,  for  the  United  States: 

1954 37 

32. — Average  value  per  acre  of  land  and  buildings  for  each  type  of  commercial  farm,  by  economic  class,  for  the  United  States:  1954_         38 
33. — Percent  distribution  of  value  of  land  and  buildings  by  type  and  economic  class  of  commercial  farms,  for  the  United  States: 

1954 38 

34. — Average  value  of  investment  in  land  and  buildings,  livestock  inventory,  machinery,  and  total  investment  for  each  type  of 

commercial  farm,  by  economic  class,  for  the  United  States:  1954 39 

35. — -Percentage  of  total  investment  by  source  for  each  type  of  commercial  farm,  by  economic  class,  for  the  United  States:   1954__         41 

36. — Percent  distribution  of  total  investment  by  economic  class  and  by  type  of  farm,  for  the  United  States:  1954 42 

37. — -Percent  distribution  of  gross  sales  for  each  type  of  farm  by  economic  class,  for  the  United  States:  1954 42 

38. — Average  value  of  farm  products  sold  per  farm  by  type  and  economic  class,  for  the  United  States:   1954 42 

39. — Value  of  all  farm  products  sold  per  acre  of  total  land  in  farms,  by  type  of  commercial  farm  by  economic  class  of  farm,  for  the 

United  States:   1954 43 

40. — Yield  per  acre  of  corn  harvested  for  grain,  by  type  of  commercial  farm  and  by  economic  class  of  farm,  for  the  United  States: 

1954 43 

41. — Value  of  all  farm  products  sold  per  $100  of  capital  invested  in  land  and  buildings,  livestock,  and  machinery,  by  type  of  com- 
mercial farm  by  economic  class  of  farm,  for  the  United  States:   1954 43 

42. — Value  of  all  farm  products  sold  per  man-equivalent  of  labor  used,  by  type  of  commercial  farm  by  economic  class  of  farm,  for 

the  United  States:  1954 44 

43. — Capital  investment  in  land  and  buildings,  livestock  and  machinery  per  man-equivalent  of  labor  used,  by  type  of  commercial 

farm  by  economic  class  of  farm,  for  the  United  States :  1954 44 

44. — Cash  farm  expenditures:  Average  per  farm  by  type  of  farm  by  economic  class,  for  the  United  States:  1955 45 

45. — Cash  farm  expenditures  as  a  percentage  of  total  farm  expenditure,  by  type  of  farm,  by  economic  class  of  farm,  for  the    United 

States:  1955 46 

46. — Percent  distribution  of  each  expenditure  by  type  of  farm,  for  the  United  States:  1955 47 

47. — -Expenses  for  purchase  and  operation  of  motor  vehicles,  farm  machinery,  and  equipment  as  a  percentage  of  total  farm  expen- 
diture, by  type  and  economic  class  of  commercial  farm,  for  the  United  States:   1955 48 

48. — Specified  farm  expenses,  average  per  farm  and  as  a  percentage  of  the  total  value  of  farm  products  sold,  by  type  of  farm  by 

economic  class,  for  the  United  States:  1954 49 

49. — Specified  group  of  farm  expense  items  as  a  percentage  of  the  total  cash  farm  expenses,  by  type  of  farm  by  economic  class,  for 

the  United  States:  1955 49 

50. — Estimated  value  added  per  farm  by  type  of  farm  by  economic  class,  for  the  United  States:   1954 50 

51. — Estimated  value  added  as  a  percent  of  the  total  value  of  farm  products  sold,  by  type  of  farm  by  economic  class:   1954 51 

52. — Estimated  value  added  per  man-equivalent  by  type  of  farm,  by  economic  class,  for  the  United  States:  1954 51 

53. — Estimated  value  added  per  $1,000  of  capital  investment  in  land  and  buildings,  machinery  and  livestock  inventory,  by  type 

of  farm  by  economic  class,  for  the  United  States :  1954 51 

54. — Percent  of  farms  reporting  electricity  by  type  of  farm  by  economic  class,  for  the  United  States:  1954 52 

55. — Index  of  specified  home  facilities,  commercial  farms  by  economic  class  and  type,  for  the  United  States:  1954 52 


4-.Mir.iti— 57 3 


AGRICULTURAL  PRODUCERS  AND  PRODUCTION  IN  THE  UNITED  STATES 

A  GENERAL  VIEW 

Jackson  V.  McElveen 
MAJOR  SECTORS  IN;  AGRICULTURE 


One  of  the  striking  features  of  American  agriculture  is  the 
diversity  of  farming — the  differences  in  crops  and  livestock  grown 
on  farms  in  various  areas,  the  wide  range  in  size  of  farms,  and  the 
contrast  in  the  way  farm  resources  are  used. 

In  a  Nation  so  vast  in  land  area,  there  are  wide  variations  in 
topography,  climate,  and  soils.  The  terrain  varies  from  alluvial 
reaches  and  flat  coastal  plains  and  prairies,  to  rolling  hills,  to 
mountain  valleys,  and  plateaus.  Soil  types  differ  in  composition 
and  fertility  and  in  their  adaptability  for  crops  and  grasses. 
Climatic  conditions  range  from  semitropical  in  the  southernmost 
parts  of  the  country  to  cooler  northern  areas  that  have  a  growing 
season  of  only  a  few  months;  and  from  the  relatively  heavy  rainfall 
of  the  East  to  some  western  regions  where  the  rainfall  can  support 
only  the  sparsest  vegetation. 

Along  with  growth  and  development  of  the  Nation's  economy, 
basic  changes  have  taken  place  that  have  created  even  greater 
differences  in  economic  environments.  Some  of  these  differences 
have  been  due  to  shifts  in  concentrations  of  population  and  mar- 
kets, to  changes  in  consumer  food  habits,  and  to  developments  in 
processing  and  transportation  of  farm  products.  Others  relate 
to  technological  improvements  in  farming  that  have  increased 
the  total  farm  production  while  reducing  the  need  for  so  many 
farm  workers. 

Differences  in  farming  over  the  United  States  are  explainable 
largely  in  terms  of  man's  efforts  in  adapting  himself  to  his  environ- 
ment. Each  farmer  makes  the  decisions  of  how  to  use  the  land, 
labor,  and  capital  resources  at  his  disposal.  His  decisions  are 
made  within  the  framework  of  his  appraisal  of  his  environment 
and  of  the  relative  advantage  of  alternative  courses  of  action. 
Because  the  environment  is  constantly  changing,  the  process  is 
never  complete  but  one  of  continuous  adjustment  to  changing 
conditions  in  both  farm  and  nonfarm  sectors  of  the  economy. 

Changes  that  affect  agriculture  have  been  particularly  rapid  in 
recent  decades.  Technological  developments  in  farming  have 
brought  about  substantial  increases  in  crop  and  livestock  yields. 
Substitution  of  tractors  for  workstock  has  meant  that  many 
acres  that  were  used  previously  to  produce  feed  for  workstock 
are  now  devoted  to  production  for  human  use.  The  result  has 
been  a  phenomenal  increase  in  farm  output. 

Mechanization  of  farming  has  enabled  a  smaller  farm  labor 
force  to  tend  and  harvest  this  larger  farm  output.  The  output 
per  man-hour  of  farm  labor  has  increased  by  nearly  3  times  since 
1910.  (See  figure  1.)  Farmers  have  been  faced  with  the  fact 
that  fewer  people  are  required  to  produce  the  foods  and  fibers  for 
a  growing  population  off  the  farms. 

At  the  same  time,  growth  and  expansion  of  the  economy  has 
provided  increasing  job  opportunities  in  the  nonfarm  sector. 
Many  farm  people,  particularly  farm  youth,  have  left  for  other 
occupations.  The  farm  population  has  decreased  by  10  million 
since  1910  and  now  comprises  only  an  eighth  of  the  total  popu- 
lation in  the  United  States.     (See  figure  2.) 


FARM  LABOR  PRODUCTIVITY 

%  OF  1947-49-! 


1910    1920    1930    1940    1950    1960 


Figure  2. 

Growth  in  the  agricultural  sector  has  been  accompanied  by 
changes  in  the  nature  and  purpose  of  individual  farm  units. 
Production  of  many  enterprises  such  as  dairying  and  poultry 
have  Income  more  specialized.  Many  farmers  have  increased 
the  scope  and  efficiency  of  their  farming  through  the  application 
of  improved  techniques.  At  the  same  time,  the  pull  of  oppor- 
tunities elsewhere  has  persuaded  others  to  reduce  the  size  of  their 
farm  businesses  and  to  take  up  work  in  nearby  towns  and  factories. 
Now  that  electrification  and  farm-to-market  roads  have  brought 
city  conveniences  to  all  but  the  remote  rural  areas,  many  city 
workers  have  moved  to  the  country.  Some  of  these  rural  residents 
raise  farm  products  for  home  use  and  incidental  sales. 


FARMERS  AND  FARM  PRODUCTION 


Included  in  the  rural  farm  population  are  many  farm  operators 
and  members  of  their  families  who  work  at  other  jobs  and  busi- 
nesses. (See  figure  3.)  More  than  2  million  farm  operators 
reported  working  off  their  farms  in  1950  and  in  1954.  Of  greater 
significance  in  respect  to  levels  of  off-farm  work,  is  the  number 
of  farm  operators  who  worked  off  the  farm  100  or  more  days. 
This  figure  indicates  that  off-farm  work  provides  a  major  source  of 
employment  and  income.  Most  of  the  farm  operators  in  this 
group  worked  off  their  farms  200  or  more  days.  While  the  number 
of  operators  working  off  their  farms  less  than  100  days  has  de- 
creased in  recent  years,  those  working  off  the  farm  100  days  or 
more  has  increased  in  each  part  of  the  country. 


Off-farm  work  of  operators  is  a  major  indication  of  the  increasing 
importance  of  nonfarm  sources  of  income  to  farm  people.  In 
addition,  many  other  members  of  the  families — wives  and  chil- 
dren— work  at  jobs  removed  from  the  farm.  Moreover,  many 
farm  people  now  receive  annuities  or  money  from  investment  funds 
and  savings  as  a  result  of  the  greater  coverage  of  the  population 
in  provisions  for  retirement  and  for  social  security,  as  well  as 
the  general  increase  in  income  levels.  The  income  to  farm  families 
from  nonfarm  sources  has  grown  steadily  since  the  1930's;  in 
1954  it  accounted  for  nearly  a  third  of  the  farm  family  income. 
(See  figure  4.) 


NUMBER  OF  FARM  OPERATORS  WORKING  OFF  THEIR  FARMS  BY  NUMBER  OF  DAYS 
^WORKED, FOR   UNITED  STATES  AND  AREAS,  1930-1954 


Figure 
Since  the  total  number  of  farms  has  been  decreasing,  the 
proportion  of  operators  working  off  farm  100  or  more  days  has 
increased  more  than  the  increase  in  the  number  alone  would 
indicate.  The  table  below  shows  this  proportion  for  the  United 
States  and  major  geographic  regions  from  Censuses  of  1930  to 
1954.  For  the  United  States  this  increase  was  from  12  percent  of 
the  farms  in  1930  to  28  percent  in  1954.  The  increase  has  been 
much  more  rapid  in  the  South  than  in  other  regions— from  11 
percent  of  the  farms  in  1930  to  30  percent  in  1954. 


Year 

Percent  of  all  farm  operators  working 
off  farm  100  or  more  days 

United 
States 

The 
North 

The 
South 

The 
West 

iml 

Percent 
11.5 
16.8 
18.4 
23.9 
28.3 

Percent 
11.1 
16.6 
17.8 
22.0 
25.3 

Percent 
10.8 
15.8 
18.1 
24.3 
29.6 

Percent 
17.8 
24.0 
27.1 
31.5 
35.2 

1949= 

1964* 

FARM  INCOME  AND  POPULATION 


— I 1 

Farm  population 
I    \ 


"MIL.  PERSONS 


A  GENERAL  VIEW 


Merging  of  farm  and  nonfarm  sectors  of  our  economy  created 
a  zone  in  farming  that  is  in  contrast  to  commercial  agriculture. 
In  this  zone  farming  provides  only  supplementary  income,  and 
farm-production  plans  are  influenced  by  considerations  that  affect 
employment  in  the  nonfarm  sector  of  the  economy. 

ECONOMIC  CLASSIFICATION  OF  FARMS 

In  delineation  of  major  sectors  in  agriculture,  a  basic  step  is 
the  separation  of  the  farms  that  are  operated  to  provide  the  major 
source  of  employment  and  income  to  the  farm  family  from  the 
places  that  serve  primarily  as  rural  homes  lor  urban  workers. 
The  economic  classification  of  farms,  developed  by  the  Bureau 
of  the  Census  and  the  Department  of  Agriculture,  separates  farms 
into  two  broad  categories — commercial  farms  and  other  farms.  The 
basis  for  separation  is  the  value  of  farm  sales,  the  off-farm  work, 
and  the  other  income  of  the  operator  family. 

In  the  economic  classification,  all  farms  with  a  value  of  farm 
products  sold  of  $1,200  or  more  were  considered  commercial 
farms.  Indications  are  that  most  of  the  farms  with  farm  sales 
above  this  amount  are  operated  to  provide  a  major  source  of 
farm-family  income.  In  addition,  farms  with  sales  of  $250  to 
$1,199  were  classified  as  commercial  provided  the  farm  operator 
was  not  employed  at  an  off -farm  job  as  much  as  100  days  during 
the  year  and  provided  the  gross  income  from  farm  sales  exceeded 
other  income  of  the  family. 

The  category  of  other  farms  includes  part-time,  residential,  and 
abnormal  farms.  Residential  farms  are  those  having  farm  sales 
of  less  than  $250.  On  these,  the  size  of  business  is  small  enough 
to  preclude  the  likelihood  of  their  being  operated  to  provide  the 
major  source  of  income  and  employment  for  the  operator  family. 
Part-time  farms  are  those  with  farm  sales  of  $250  to  $1,199  but 
whose  operators  work  100  or  more  days  of  the  year  at  a  nonfarm 
job,  or  report  that  income  received  by  the  family  from  other 
sources  is  greater  than  sales  from  the  farm.  Abnormal  farms  are 
mainly  public  and  private  institutional  farms,  such  as  college, 
prison,  community,  experiment  station  farms,  and  grazing  asso- 
ciations. 

The  separation  of  commercial  farms  from  those  that  are  part- 
time  and  residential  defines  two  distinct  sectors  within  agriculture 
with  marked  differences  in  economic  interests.  Commercial 
farms  are  the  going  concerns  in  agriculture  that  produce  virtually 
all  of  the  farm  products  for  sale.  The  separation  of  this  group 
of  farms  for  special  study  provides  an  improved  basis  for  analysis 
of  production  problems  and  gives  greater  form  and  meaning  to 
comparisons  of  income  and  of  efficiency  within  agriculture  and 
between  farm  and  nonfarm  sectors  of  the  economy. 

Commercial  and  Noncommercial  Farms 

The  other  or  noncommercial  farms  are  numerous,  accounting 
for  approximately  a  third  of  all  farms  in  the  United  States  in 
1954.     (See  table  below.) 


Classification 

Number 
of  farms 

Land  in 

Cropland 

harvard 

Value  of 

land  and 
bmldincs 

Value  of 

pmdiirls 
sold 

Percent 
100.0 

69.6 
30.4 

Percent 
100.0 

89.0 

Percent 
100.0 

96.2 
3.8 

Percent 
100.0 

87.9 
12.1 

Percent 

Activity  on  these  farms  is  not  oriented  to  commercial  agriculture. 
This  is  supported  best  by  the  relatively  small  volume  of  farm  sales, 
which  amounted  to  less  than  2  percent  of  all  farm  products  sold. 
Commercial  farms  comprised  over  two-thirds  of  the  total  number 
of  farms  and  accounted  for  89  percent  of  the  land  in  farms,  96 
percent  of  the  cropland  harvested,  88  percent  of  the  investment  in 
land  and  buildings,  and  produced  98percenl  of  the  market  sales  in 
1954. 

The  total  number  of  farms  has  decreased  from  6.3  million  in  1930 
to  4.8  million  in  1954,  a  decrease  of  1.5  million.  (See  figure  5.) 
Commercial  farms  have  declined  by  1.6  million  which  is  at  a  more 
rapid  rate  than  the  decrease  in  all  farms.  •  The  decrease  in  com- 
mercial farms  has  been  partly  offset  by  an  increase  in  part-time 
and  residential  units.  A  substantial  part  of  the  decrease  in  farm 
numbers  between  1930  and  1954  was  among  the  small  subsistence 
units.  These  are  places  that  have  farm  sales  of  less  then  $250 
and  no  apparent  sources  of  income  other  than  from  the  farm. 


U.  S.  FARMS 


1950        1954 


Figure  5. 

Part-time  and  residential  farms. — The  increase  in  part-time 
farming  is  the  result  of  numerous  factors  associated  with  general 
growth  and  development  of  both  farm  and  nonfarm  sectors  of  the 
economy.  Farmers  have  not  shared  equally  in  the  benefits  from 
improved  technology.  Hilly  land  and  small  fields  limited  the 
adaptability  of  machines  in  some  areas.  Many  operators  of  small 
farms  have  not  found  it  economic  to  use  even  the  smallest  of  the 
tractors  and  machines.  At  the  same  time,  there  has  been  a 
tremendous  increape  in  retail  and  other  services  in  rural  areas 
because  of  the  increasing  proportion  of  farm  inputs  being  bought 
by  farmers  as  well  as  the  larger  disposable  incomes  of  farm  people. 
This,  along  with  continued  expansion  of  industries  in  the  open 
country  and  small  towns  has  provided  local  alternatives  to  farming. 

Earnings  from  farming  on  some  of  the  smaller  units  were  less 
than  nonfarm  wages,  so  farmers  and  members  of  their  families 
took  advantage  of  attractive  jobs  nearby.  Many  continued  to 
farm  while  commuting  to  other  work  nearby. 

Part-time  and  residential  farms  are  located  in  most  parts  of  the 
country,  but  are  most  numerous  in  the  South.  Concentrations  are 
noticeable  throughout  the  Appalachian  and  Cumberland  Moun- 
tains and  in  the  vicinity  of  many  of  the  larger  cities. 

'  The  data  In  figure  5  are  not  entirely  comparable  with  the  current  Census  economic  classification  since  the  criteria  for  separation  of  part-time  from  commercial  were  applied  to 
farms  in  the  $1,200  to  $2,499  value  group.  See  McElveen,  J.  V.,  Family  Farms  in  a  Changing  Economy.  Agriculture  Information  Bulletin  171,  Economics  Research  Division,  ARS, 
USDA,  March  1957. 


10 


FARMERS  AND  FARM  PRODUCTION 


f^^p^-^-pJGROSS  SALES  $ 

UNITED  STATES  TOTAL                  \ 
574. 575                               \ 

PART-TIME 

250  TO  SI.I99-F 

NUMBER. 

i  aw; 

JCTS  MINOR  SOURCE  OF  INCOME*) 

Si 

fV 

100  FARMS             \       1 

1=^ 

^ 

^vf 

inr 

|    *?— 

RESIDENTIAL    FARMS 

(GROSS   SALES  LESS  THAtJ  $250) 
NUMBER.  1951 

rv. 

L^~4~ 

p  .^'f^ 

J~~~tu 

;■--  1 

•■"m 

'-€.: 

V 

UNITED   STATES    TOTAL 
878.  136 

\ 

\ 

W 

IDOT- 100  FARMS                V^ 

>L  ._ 

Figure  7. 

The  higher  incidence  of  part-time  and  residential  farms  in  the 
SoutrTis  owing  partly  to  the  more  recent  industrial  development 
there.  Growth  in  manufacturing,  in  industries,  and  in  trades  and 
services  coincided  with  other  developments  such  as  improvement 
of  roads  and  the  prevailing  use  of  automobiles,  which  made  it 
possible  for  farm  people  to  commute  to  jobs  in  town,  while  con- 
tinuing to  live  on  the  farms.  Rural  electrification  made  city 
conveniences  possible  in  many  rural  homes  and  reduced  some  of 
the  incentive  for  moving  to  town.  An  important  factor  has  been 
the  tendency  of  the  manufacturing  industries  in  the  South  to 
decentralize  by  locating  their  plants  throughout  many  semirural 
areas.  Also,  the  South  contains  a  higher  proportion  of  small,  low- 
income  farms  than  other  broad  regions  of  the  country.  Farm 
families  on  these  small  farms  have  probably  had  the  greatest 
incentive  to  supplement  their  incomes  through  off-farm  work. 

A  detailed  analysis  of  part-time  farming  appears  in  chapter  S 
of  this  report. 

Commercial  farms. — Commercial  farms  have  a  more  general 
and  widespread  distribution  over  the  United  States  than  is  true 
of  the  noncommercial  farm  categories.  In  most  areas  east  of 
the  100th  meridian  there  is  a  uniform  and  fairly  heavy  concen- 
tration of  commercial  farms.  The  density  in  the  Mississippi 
River  flood  plains  of  Arkansas  and  Mississippi,  the  tobacco 
country  of  the  Carolinas,  and  other  scattered  locations,  reflect 
the  larger  numbers  of  small  farms  in  these  areas.  The  Corn  Belt 
States  of  Iowa,  Indiana,  Illinois,  and  Ohio  have  a  uniformly 
heavy  concentration  of  commercial  farms  that  is  due  to  the  high 
proportion  of  land  open  and  suitable  for  farming. 


COMMERCIAL   FARMS 


IDOT. 500  FARMS 


X) 


The  small  number  of  commercial  farms  in  most  of  the  western 
half  of  the  United  States  reflects  the  low  average  productivity 
of  a  region  that  has  rough  terrain  and  limited  rainfall.  The 
farms  are  large,  on  the  average,  except  where  irrigation  has  been 
developed.  In  the  West,  wherever  large  numbers  of  farms  are 
clustered,  the  presence  of  irrigation  is  indicated.  Exceptions 
are  the  Willamette  Valley  of  Oregon  and  the  Puget  Sound  country 
of  Washington,  where  rainfall  is  sufficient  to  allow  a  variety  of 
crops  to  be  grown  without  irrigation. 

Economic  Classes  of  Commercial  Farms 

The  commercial  farms  are  divided  into  six  economic  classes  on 
the  basis  of  the  value  of  farm  products  sold.  The  criteria  for 
separating  commercial  from  noncommercial  farms  and  for  deline- 
ating the  economic  classes  of  commercial  farms  are  shown  in  the 
table  which  follows. 


Criteria 

Economic  class  of  farm 

Value  of  farm  products 
sold 

Other 

$25,001)  or  more 

$10, I  to  $24,099 

$:i.oiio  to  $9,999 

$2, .Mill  to  $1,999 

$1,200  to  $2,499 

Class  III 

None' 

by  operator  and  income  of  opera- 
tor and  members  of  his  family 
from  nonfarm  sources  less  than 
value  of  all  farm  products  sold. 

Total  of  categories  below. 

more  days  or  other  incomo  of 
family  greater  than  value  of  all 
farm  products  Sold. 

Public  and  private  institutional 
farms,  experiment  stations,  etc. 

Economic  class  as  a  measure  of  farm  size. — One  of  the  major 
uses  of  the  economic  classes  of  commercial  farms  is  in  broad 
analysis  of  the  structure  of  farming.  Information  is  needed  on 
the  extent  to  which  producers  on  different  sizes  of  farms  have 
been  able  to  make  adjustments  in  production  and  take  advantage 
of  new  techniques  that  have  proved  efficient.  The  economic 
classification,  being  based  on  gross  sales  of  farm  products,  also 
provides  an  indirect  measure  of  relative  levels  of  farm  income  and 
its  distribution. 


A  GENERAL  VIEW 


11 


There  is  today  a  great  public  interest  in  the  size  structure  of 
farming.  This  is  because  of  a  real  concern  about  the  future  of 
family-type  farms.  These  are  farms  on  which  the  management 
and  most  of  the  capital  and  labor  are  furnished  by  the  operator 
and  members  of  his  family.  The  apparent  growth  in  the  size  of 
farms  and  the  reduction  in  the  number  of  farms  in  recent  years, 
have  made  people  wonder  whether  the  family  type  of  farm  is 
declining  in  importance  as  the  major  production  unit  in  the 
Nation's  agriculture.  As  farming  on  a  commercial  scale  today  re- 
quires large  capital  investments,  a  question  is  raised  as  to  the 
ability  of  farm  families  to  compete  in  the  adopt  inn  of  new 
techniques  designed  to  increase  efficiency  and  output. 

Table  1. — Farms  and  Specified  Farm  Resources  by  Eco- 
nomic Class  of  Commercial  Farm,  for  the  United  States: 
1954 


Number 

of  farms 

Average  per  farm 

Economic  class  of  farm 

Land  in 

Value  of 
land  and 
buildings 

Expend- 
iture fin- 
bbed 
labor 

Value  of 
farm 

product-: 

sold 

Thou- 

3,328 
134 
449 
707 
812 
764 
463 

Acres 
310.3 

1,939.1 
537.8 
311.9 
201.0 
134.3 

Dollars 
25.  429 

134.  169 
51,610 
27,  992 
15.880 

6^096 

Dollars 
665 
8,342 
1,166 
422 
214 
106 
43 

Dollars 
7,302 

57,  997 
14,883 
7,178 

756 

Percentage  distribution 

100.0 
4.0 
13.5 
21.2 
24  4 
22.9 
13.9 

100.0 
25.2 
23.4 
21.4 
15.8 
9.9 

100.0 

22.2 
27.4 

15!  T 
8.8 
3.3 

100.0 
50.5 
23.6 
13.5 
7.8 
3.7 
0.9 

100  0 

27^5 
20.9 
12.4 
5.8 

Class  I  farms  represent  the  relatively  few  large  operations  that 
had  gross  sales  of  $25,000  or  more  in  1954.  As  a  group,  these 
farms  are  characterized  by  large  acreages  and  large  investments  in 
land  and  buildings.  They  use  considerable  hired  labor.  The 
average  wage  bill  amounted  to  $8,342  per  farm  in  1954.  Although 
comprising  only  4  percent  of  the  commercial  farms,  Class  I  farms 
accounted  for  25  percent  of  the  land  in  farms  and  22  percent  of 
the  investment  in  land  and  buildings.  They  produced  nearly  a 
third  of  the  farm  products  sold  in  1954. 

Economic  Classes  II,  III,  and  IV  represent,  by  and  large,  the 
medium  to  high  income  family  farms  that  are  an  outstanding 
characteristic  of  American  agriculture.  They  cover  a  fairly  wide 
range  in  value  of  farm  products  sold,  from  $2,500  to  $24,999. 
These  farms  as  a  group  comprise  the  largest  segment  of  commercial 
agriculture  in  respect  to  both  numbers  and  value  of  production. 

Class  V  farms  had  sales  of  farm  products  that  ranged  from  $1,200 
to  $2,499.  Class  VI  farms  sold  between  $250  and  $1,199  of  farm 
products.  By  definition,  operators  of  Class  VI  farms  did  not  work 
off  the  farm  as  much  as  100  days  during  the  year  and  gross  farm 
sales  exceeded  the  income  of  the  farmer  and  his  family  from  off- 
farm  sources.  Although  farms  in  these  two  classes  comprised  37 
percent  of  the  commercial  farms,  they  accounted  for  only  7  percent 
of  the  sales  of  all  farm  products.    The  small  size  of  farm  business 


on  these  farms  is  indicated  by  the  relatively  small  acreage  and 
small  investment  in  land  and  buildings. 

Geographic  distribution  of  economic  classes. — The  geographic 
distribution  of  each  of  the  six  economic  classes  of  Commercial  farms 
is  shown  on  the  accompanying  maps. 

Class  I  farms  are  most  numerous  in  Illinois,  Iowa,  the  High 
Plains  of  Texas,  and  the  irrigated  parts  of  California.  Many 
Class  I  farms,  particularly  in  Iowa  and  Illinois,  are  livestock  farms. 
Many  of  these  purchase  cattle  and  hogs  for  fattening.  Farms  with 
gross  sales  of  $25,000  are  not  considered  large  for  this  type  of  farm 
and  the  net  income  may  be  no  larger  than  that  received  on  many 
of  the  smaller  economic  classes  in  other  types  of  farming. 


ECONOMIC    CLASS 


Figure 


The  Corn  Belt  is  the  broad  area  of  greatest  density  of  Class  II 
farms.  Many  farms  in  this  class  are  also  found  in  the  Northeast, 
in  the  Plains  States,  and  in  the  Pacific  Coast  States.  Class  III 
farms  are  widely  distributed  in  the  North.  Class  IV  farms  are 
fairly  uniformly  distributed  throughout  the  entire  country, 
although  a  heavy  concentration  of  them  is  noticeable  in  the 
tobacco  sections  of  the  Carolinas.  Economic  Classes  V  and  VI 
are  much  more  numerous  in  the  South  where  they  are  likely  to  be 
associated  primarily  with  the  growing  of  cotton  and  tobacco. 


ECONOMIC    CLASS  II   FARMS 


12 


FARMERS  AND  FARM  PRODUCTION 


ECONOMIC    CLASS  III  FARMS 

SALES  OF  1 

NUMBER.  1954 


\-''f  IDOT. 100  FARMS  Ni^     '<■ 

■  1      mxm  uN"Ms*'       v 


ECONOMIC 

•  .  -1 ;  I 

CLASS 

OF  $2.50 

V  FARMS 

)  TO  $4,999] 

■•■■  #- 

UNITEO  STATES 
811.969 

TOTAL 

V/~xl 

T 

*'%.       ■- 

5. 

PI 

ECONOMIC    CLASS  V  FARMS 

__ NUMBER  J954                                                                         r^\ 

H 

^T^Zj 

UN.TE 

763.348 

Vy~^                p ' 

OOT-IOO  FARMS                V       \ 

w 

ECONOMIC    CLASS  VI  FARMS 

SALES   OF  $250  TO  $1.199- FARM  PRODUCTS   MAJOR   SOURCE   OF  INCOME*) 
NUMBER .  1954                                                                       r^\ 

1} 

["j        /i^O^s-.             rr^K/ 

t\A 

~-:~-L-      '-.        V--^''"'^ 

UNITED    STATES   TOTAL 

462.427 

V/~n              >        •   -        '"     1     \ 

*™£HS 

tomtsop'eSte'.  ™'n*°Bvi    '    Jf             1  DOT.  100  FARMS                 I        1 
SOURCES                                     ^O  A                     (COUNTY  UNIT  SfiSlSI                          \i 

Characteristics  and  limitations  of  the  economic  classification. — 
The  economic  classification  is  subject  to  certain  characteristics 
which  need  to  be  considered  when  they  are  used.  Probably  the 
most  important  consideration  is  that  classification  on  the  basis  of 
gross  sales  rather  than  net  value  of  production  fails  to  take  account, 
of  differences  in  purchased  inputs.  This  needs  to  be  considered 
when  comparisons  are  made  between  different  types  of  farms. 

In  addition,  the  classification  is  based  on  one  year's  sales  of 
farm  products.  For  the  purpose  of  providing  a  picture  of  the 
normal  size  of  farms,  this  may  not  give  an  accurate  picture  of  any 
farm  that,  because  of  chance  factors,  had  higher  or  lower  than 
normal  yields  or  sales  from  inventories.  The  market  output  of 
an  individual  farm  may  vary  considerably  from  year  to  year  even 
though  the  farm  organization  remains  relatively  stable  over  a 
period  of  years  in  respect  to  capital,  labor,  and  enterprises.  This 
may  be  because  of  fluctuations  in  yield  that  arise  through  vagaries 
in  weather  or  through  higher  or  lower  than  normal  sales  of  live- 
stock. Thus,  it  is  possible  for  farms  with  fairly  similar  levels  of 
production  over  the  average  of  several  years  to  fall  in  different 
classes  when  classified  on  the  basis  of  sales  in  a  given  year. 

TYPES  OF  COMMERCIAL  FARMS 

The  commercial  farms  are  divided  into  types  on  the  basis  of 
the  proportion  of  gross  sales  accounted  for  by  sales  of  various 
commodities.  In  general,  a  farm  was  placed  in  a  particular  com- 
modity type  if  gross  sales  of  the  particular  commodity  or  group 
of  commodities  accounted  for  as  much  as  50  percent  of  the  total 
gross  sales  from  the  farm.  In  some  cases  the  type  of  farm  was 
determined  on  the  basis  of  the  sale  of  an  individual  farm  product, 
such  as  cotton,  or  on  the  basis  of  closely  related  products,  such  as 
dairy  products.  In  other  cases  the  type  was  determined  on  the 
basis  of  a  broader  group  of  products  such  as  corn,  sorghums,  small 
grains,  field  beans,  field  peas,  cowpeas,  and  soybeans.  When  the 
value  of  products  from  one  source  or  group  of  sources  did  not 
represent  as  much  as  50  percent  of  the  total  value  of  all  farm  prod- 
ucts sold,  the  farms  were  classified  as  general. 


A  GENERAL  VIEW 


13 


The  information  on  farm  sales  was  only  for  the  year  specified. 
Many  farms  get  a  major  part  of  their  income  from  sales  of  two  or 
more  of  the  commodities  used  in  the  criteria  for  determining  type. 
For  these  farms,  classification  by  type  in  the  particular  year  may 
be  influenced  to  some  extent  by  chance  factors,  such  as  the  price 
relationships  between  commodities  in  the  particular  year  and 
abnormalities  in  crop  yield  or  changes  in  livestock  inventories. 

In  the  classification  by  type  of  farm,  no  recognition  is  given  to 
products  produced  but  not  sold  from  the  farm. 

A  measure  of  commodity  specialization. — The  separation  of 
commercial  farms  by  type  of  farm  identifies  the  major  producers 
of  commodities  or  commodity  groups.  The  criteria  for  determin- 
ing type  required  that  50  percent  or  more  of  the  farm  income  be 
derived  from  a  particular  source.  Most  types  represent  a  fairly 
high  degree  of  specialization  among  the  producers  classified.  In 
consideration  of  problems  in  the  production  of  specific  commodities, 
this  permits  analysis  of  the  farm  organizations,  efficiency  and 
income  of  the  producers  involved,  as  well  as  identification  of  the 
areas  of  the  country  most  affected.  It  makes  possible  a  more 
meaningful  appraisal  of  public  policies  and  of  the  probable  effects 
of  alternative  programs  of  assistance. 

The  number  and  proportions  of  the  commercial  farms  by  type 
of  farm  are  shown  in  the  table  below. 


Type  of  farm 

N'umbor 
of  farms 

Percent 
distribu- 
tion 

537,  974 
525.  463 
367,  7:5:! 
32,  581 
82.  096 

548,  767 
154.  251 

..■i|    NS.H 
347.  079 
37.  057 

16  2 

16  5 

3,  327,  889 

100  0 

Geographic  Distribution  of  Types  of  Farms 

Cash-grain  farms. — Out  of  3.3  million  commercial  farms,  more 
than  a  half-million  are  cash-grain  farms.  Cash-grain  farms  are 
those  on  which  the  value  of  farm  sales  from  corn,  sorghums,  small 
grains,  soybeans,  cowpeas,  and  dry  field  beans  and  peas  was  equal 
to  50  percent  or  more  of  the  total  value  of  all  farm  products  sold. 


The  geographic  distribution  of  cash-grain  farms  is  shown  on  the 
map  below.  Concentrations  of  these  farms  are  noticeable  in 
arras  where  one  or  more  of  the  cash  grains  are  a  predominate  crop. 
In  the  IJakotas,  Montana,  Idaho,  and  Oregon,  cash-grain  farms 
are  primarily  spring  wheat  farms.  Farther  south,  in  Nebraska, 
Kansas,  western  Oklahoma,  and  the  northern  Panhandle  of  Texas, 
winter  wheat  was  the  grain  crop  that  determined  the  type.  In 
the  Corn  Belt  States  of  Iowa,  Illinois,  Indiana,  and  Ohio,  cash- 
grain  farms  represent  largely  corn  and  soybean  farms.  Cash- 
grain  farms  in  the  Gulf  Coast  of  Louisiana  and  Texas,  the  Arkansas 
Prairies,  and  the  Sacramento  Valley  of  California,  include  many 
rice  farms.  In  scattered  localities  the  major  source  of  income  on 
cash-grain  farms  is  from  sorghum,  dry  field  beans  and  peas,  and 
small  grains  other  than  wheat  and  rice,  but  these  farms  are  rela- 
tively unimportant  numerically. 

Cotton  farms. — Cotton  farms  are  those  on  which  50  percent 
or  more  of  the  sales  of  all  farm  products  was  from  sales  of  cotton. 
The  line  crop,  cotton,  was  the  major  source  of  farm  sales  on  slightly 
more  than  one-half  million  farms,  or  about  16  percent  of  the 
commercial  farms  in  1954.  Cotton  farms  are  located  almost 
entirely  in  the  South  and  in  selected  irrigated  areas  of  Texas,  New 
Mexico,  Arizona,  and  California.  (See  map  below.)  The  northern 
extent  of  cotton  production  is  limited  sharply  by  temperature  and 
length  of  growing  season.  In  general,  rainfall  is  insufficient  in 
the  Southwest  so  cotton  can  be  grown  only  if  irrigated. 

The  heaviest  centers  of  concentration  appear  in  the  Mississippi 
and  Arkansas  deltas,  in  the  Upper  Piedmont  and  Coastal  Plains 
of  North  Carolina,  South  Carolina,  Georgia,  Alabama,  and 
Mississippi,  and  the  Black  Prairie  of  east  central  Texas.  Other 
concentrations  are  found  in  southwestern  Oklahoma  and  the  high 
plains  and  lower  Rio  Grande  Valley  of  Texas. 


Figure  10. 

Other  field-crop  farms. — Farms  were  classified  in  this  category 
whenever  the  value  of  sales  of  a  variety  of  major  and  minor  crops 
accounted  for  50  percent  or  more  of  the  total  value  of  all  farm 
products  sold.  These  crops  include  tobacco,  peanuts,  potatoes, 
sugar  beets,  sugarcane,  and  other  specialty  field  crops  except 
cotton.  No  one  area  has  all  these  crops.  In  areas  where  one  or 
more  of  them  are  grown,  usually  one  tends  to  predominate.  This 
makes  it  possible  to  identify  the  "other  field-crop"  farms  in  most 
areas  as  a  more  specific  type,  such  as  tobacco  farms  or  peanut 
farms. 


4i:.".irji;     r,7 


14 


FARMERS  AND  FARM  PRODUCTION 


Slightly  more  than  10  percent  of  the  commercial  farms  were 
classified  as  other  field-crop  farms  in  1954.  These  farms  are 
heavily  concentrated  in  the  Appalachian  and  southeastern  States 
(see  map  below).  Tobacco  is  the  most  important  type-deter- 
mining crop.  Farms  on  which  the  sale  of  tobacco  was  the  major 
source  of  farm  sales  accounted  for  more  than  two-thirds  of  the 
other  field-crop  farms  in  1954.  Burley  and  fire-cured  tobacco 
farms  account  for  most  of  the  other  field-crop  farms  in  Kentucky, 
Tennessee,  and  western  North  Carolina.  In  the  eastern  Carolinas 
and  Virginia,  flue-cured  tobacco  predominates,  although  peanuts 
are  grown  along  the  coast  of  Virginia  and  North  Carolina.  The 
concentration  of  other  field-crop  farms  in  Georgia  and  Alabama 
represent  primarily  peanuts  in  Alabama  and  a  mixture  of  peanuts 
and  tobacco  in  Georgia. 


VV«^_                                    OTHER  FIELD-  CROP  FARMS 

Hr  ^~~~~TT^^.                                         NUMBER.  1954 

—  Aj4^T^fj£r 

UNITH)  STATES  TOTAL                     V/~\                   '    !K^-%i>S              ^1     \ 

367,771                                               \       ■.     -S                                                  I      \ 

\        f            ID0T-I0O  FARMS                  \       ] 

Figure  17. 

Concentrations  of  other  field-crop  farms  include  potato  farms 
in  Aroostook  County,  Maine,  and  sugarcane  farms  in  Louisiana. 
In  the  Red  River  Valley  area  of  Minnesota  and  North  Dakota,  and 
in  scattered  western  areas,  potatoes  and  sugar  beets  are  grown  in 
the  same  areas  and  frequently  on  the  same  farms. 

Vegetable  farms. — Farms  on  which  the  value  of  all  vegetables 
sold  comprised  50  percent  or  more  of  the  total  farm  products  sold 
were  classified  as  vegetable  farms.  They  account  for  only  1  per- 
cent of  the  commercial  farms.  Many  farms  that  grow  vegetables 
for  sale  do  not  grow  enough  to  fall  in  this  specialized  category. 

Important  localized  areas  of  vegetable  farms  are  found  in  many 
States  across  the  Continent.  (See  map  below.)  Particular  areas 
of  concentration  are  Long  Island,  the  Florida  Peninsula,  the  lower 
Rio  Grande  Valley  of  Texas,  southwest  Arizona,  and  the  area 
adjacent  to  San  Francisco  Bay. 


^TT- 

VEGETABLE    FARMS 
NUMBER.  1954 

I  /pL-Ji 

W     Y        j~     F 

UMTED  STATES  TOTAL                     Xy~ 
32.561 

ARMS               S.  '] 

Fruit-and-nut  farms. — Like  vegetable  farms,  the  fruit-and- 
nut  farms  comprise  one  of  the  less  numerous  types.  As  fruit 
production  on  a  commercial  scale  is  largely  restricted  to  areas 
having  favorable  conditions  in  respect  to  temperature,  air  drainage, 
and  soil  moisture,  fruit-and-nut  farms  are  highly  concentrated  in 
a  few  localities.  (See  map  below.)  The  most  important  are  found 
in  California,  Oregon,  Washington,  Michigan,  New  York,  Florida, 
and  Texas. 


Dairy  farms. — Dairying  is  one  of  the  more  important  types  of 
farming.  More  than  one-half  million  farms,  comprising  nearly  17 
percent  of  the  commercial  farms,  were  classified  as  dairy  farms 
in  1954.  Farms  were  so  classified  if  50  percent  or  more  of  the 
total  sales  of  farm  products  were  milk  or  other  dairy  products; 
or,  if  50  percent  of  the  cows  on  hand  were  milk  cows,  sales  of 
dairy  products  of  30  percent  was  sufficient,  if  together  with  sales 
of  cattle  and  calves  the  two  sources  accounted  for  50  percent  of 
the  total  sales  of  farm  products. 

The  principal  areas  of  concentration  of  dairy  producers  are  the 
Northeast,  the  Lake  States,  and  the  Pacific  Coast  States.  (See 
map  below.)  Smaller  areas  of  concentration  are  the  Central 
Basin  of  Tennessee,  southwestern  Missouri,  and  the  Lower  Snake 
River  country  of  Idaho.  Other  localized  concentrations  are  found 
around  most  of  the  larger  cities  everywhere  and  are  referred  to 
frequently  as  local  milksheds. 


A  GENERAL  VIEW 


15 


Poultry  farms. — Sales  of  chickens  and  eggs  from  the  home  flock 
is  one  of  the  most  common  sources  of  farm  sales  to  farmers.  In 
few  cases,  are  these  sales  large  enough  to  comprise  the  50  percent 
of  total  sales  of  farm  products  needed  to  classify  farms  as  poultry 
farms.  Of  all  commercial  farms,  slightly  less  than  5  percent  were 
poultry  farms. 

In  general,  poultry  producers  are  most  numerous  in  the  north- 
eastern quarter  of  the  United  States.  (Sec  map  below.)  In  this 
broad  region,  particular  areas  of  concentration  are  shown  in  the 
Delmarva  Peninsula,  New  Jersey,  southeastern  Pennsylvania, 
and  the  three  southern  New  England  States.  In  the  southeastern 
part  of  the  United  States,  concentrations  of  poultry  farms  appear 
in  a  few  widely  scattered  localities.  Particularly  noticeable  are 
the  places  of  broiler  production  in  Georgia,  North  Carolina,  and 
the  northwestern  part  of  Arkansas.  Poultry  farms  are  relatively 
scarce  in  the  West  except  in  the  Pacific  Coast  States. 


UMTED  STATES  TOTAL 
154.257 

POULTRY    FARMS 

Mi 

\j 

\        f            IDOT.IOO  FARMS 

Figure  21. 

Livestock  farms  other  than  dairy  and  poultry. — These  farms, 
taken  together,  are  the  most  numerous  type  in  the  United  States. 
Over  a  fifth  of  the  commercial  farms  (695,000)  were  classified  as 
livestock  farms  in  1954.  Farms  were  so  classified  if  the  total 
combined  sales  of  cattle,  hogs,  sheep,  goats,  wool,  mohair,  goat 
milk,  and  products  from  animals  slaughtered  on  the  farm  ac- 
counted for  50  percent  or  more  of  the  total  sales  of  farm  products 
(provided  the  farm  did  not  classify  as  a  dairy  farm). 

Livestock  farms  show  a  widespread  and  fairly  uniform  dis- 
tribution over  the  country  (see  map  below).  The  areas  of  greatest 
concentration  are  in  Iowa,  northern  Missouri,  and  western 
Illinois.  Central  Indiana,  southwestern  Ohio,  and  northeastern 
Nebraska  show  areas  of  almost  equal  concentration  but  of  smaller 
geographic  scope.  These  States  comprise  what  is  known  as  the 
Corn  Belt  where  large  quantities  of  feed  grains  are  grown  and  the 
fattening  of  hogs  and  cattle  is  the  dominant  farm  enterprise. 

Livestock  farms  in  other  parts  of  the  country  may  vary  from 
vast  ranches  in  the  arid  West,  which  may  require  40  or  more  acres 
per  animal  unit,  to  farms  in  some  areas  of  the  South,  which 
occasionally  have  improved  pastures  that  will  carry  an  animal 
unit  on  1  or  2  acres.  Because  of  the  large  acreages  required  per 
animal  unit  in  the  Western  States,  livestock  farms  are  sparsely 
distributed  even  though  they  are  the  most  important  type  from 
the  standpoint  of  numbers.  Many  livestock  farms  in  the  Appa- 
lachian and  southeastern  parts  of  the  country  are  small  farms  of  a 
subsistence  type  where  small  sales  of  cattle  and  hogs  are  the  main 
farm  sales. 


General  farms. — Farms  were  classified  as  general  when  none 
of  the  specified  commodities  or  commodity  groups  accounted  for 
as  much  as  50  percent  of  gross  farm  sales.  The  Census  of  Agri- 
culture provides  data  for  three  types  of  general  farms.  These  are 
(1)  primarily  crop,  (2)  primarily  livestock,  and  (3)  crop  and 
livestock. 

As  a  group,  general  farms  account  for  10  percent  of  the  com- 
mercial farms.  Their  geographic  distribution  is  more  uniform 
over  the  United  States  than  any  other  type  (see  map  below). 
Relatively  heavy  concentrations  are  found  in  areas  that  are  transi- 
tional between  the  more  specialized  farming  areas;  there  general 
farms  are  likely  to  be  less  specialized  versions  of  the  major  types. 
The  combination  of  livestock  production  with  the  growing  of  grains 
is  the  most  frequent  reason  for  farms  being  classified  as  general. 
In  the  Plains  States,  for  example,  wheat  production  is  often  com- 
bined with  cattle  raising  or  fattening.  Farther  east,  hog  and  beef 
fattening  is  combined  with  dairying  and  with  growing  corn  and 
other  feed  grains.  Livestock  is  produced  along  with  tobacco  in 
the  burley  and  fire-cured  tobacco  country  of  Kentucky  and  Ten- 
nessee, and  with  cotton  throughout  the  Southeast.  More  than 
three-fourths  of  the  general  farms  were  classified  as  primarily 
livestock  or  crop  and  livestock. 


16 


FARMERS  AND  FARM  PRODUCTION 


Miscellaneous  farms. — This  category  includes  relatively  un- 
important types  as  to  number,  such  as  forest-products  farms,  horse 
farms,  nurseries,  and  greenhouses.  Taken  together,  these  farms 
accounted  for  only  1  percent  of  all  commercial  farms.  The  main 
purpose  in  classifying  miscellaneous  farms  was  to  exclude  them 
from  the  other  types  in  order  that  the  classification  would  be  more 
meaningful. 

Type-of'Farming  Areas 

Any  attempt  to  outline  type-of-farming  areas  in  the  United 
States  must  necessarily  be  very  general.  It  is  typical  in  some 
regions  that  a  particular  type  of  farm  predominates,  but  other 
regions  are  characterized  by  a  mixture  of  types,  none  of  which 
predominate  numerically. 

The  accompanying  map  shows  the  type  of  farm  that  accounted 
for  50  percent  or  more  of  the  commercial  farms  in  each  county 
for  1954.  (See  map  below.)  Mixed-farming  counties  are  those  in 
which  no  single  type  comprised  as  much  as  half  the  commercial 
farms. 

On  this  basis,  several  major  type-of-farming  areas  stand  out: 
The  dairy  areas  of  New  England  and  the  Lake  States;  the  tobacco 
areas  of  North  Carolina  and  Kentucky;  the  cotton  area  which 
covers  most  of  the  South  as  well  as  parts  of  Texas,  New  Mexico, 
Arizona,  and  California;  the  livestock  areas  which  predominate 


in  the  West  and  extend  into  the  Midwest;  the  cash-grain  areas 
of  the  Midwest,  North  Dakota,  Kansas,  and  the  Northwest;  and 
the  fruit-and-nut  areas  of  central  California  and  the  Florida 
peninsula.  In  addition  to  these,  there  are  many  smaller  areas 
in  which  certain  types  of  farms  predominate. 

But  the  mixed  areas  cover  a  greater  geographic  extent  than 
does  any  specific  type.  These  usually  border  the  more  specialized 
areas.  In  some  instances  they  are  transitional  areas  in  which  two 
or  more  major  types  of  farming  merge.  In  this  respect,  it  is 
interesting  to  observe  the  mixed  nature  of  farming  in  the  Mid- 
west, long  known  for  its  corn,  hogs,  and  cattle  feeding.  With  the 
exception  of  livestock  areas  of  Iowa  and  Missouri  and  the  cash- 
grain  areas  of  Illinois  and  Indiana,  this  region  appears  as  pre- 
dominately a  mixed-farming  area.  Production  of  feed  grains  and 
feeding  of  livestock  are  interrelated  to  the  extent  that  neither 
enterprise  predominates  in  most  of  this  region. 

In  reviewing  the  type-of-farming  area  maps  shown  here,  it  must 
be  recalled  that  they  are  based  upon  numbers  of  farms  having  a 
major  source  of  income  from  a  particular  source.  For  this  reason, 
type-of-farming  areas  may  not  represent  the  major  source  of  in- 
come for  the  area.  This  would  be  true  in  cases  in  which  relatively 
small  numbers  of  farms  with  large  sales  volumes  were  of  basically 
different  types.  In  most  situations  a  cash-grain  or  dairy  area, 
for  example,  will  approximate  the  area  outlined  by  the  major 
source  of  income. 


TYPE-OF-FARMING    AREAS, BASED   ON   TYPE    ACCOUNTING  FOR   50  PERCENT 
OR  MORE    OF  COMMERCIAL  FARMS,  1954 


LEGEND 
TYPE-OF-FARMING    AREA 
Hsl  CASH-GRAIN  BSSS  DAIRY 

[~1  COTTON  M  POULTRY 

PH OTHER    FIELD-CROP  I^H  LIVESTOCK  (OTHER  THAN 

L     J  VEGETABLE 

«_„  LZA  GENERAL    (NO  ONE    TYPE 

MS  FRUIT-AND-NUT  50   pERCENT    0R 


A  GENERAL  VIEW 


17 


TYPE  OF  FARM  BY  ECONOMIC  CLASS 

Substantial  differences  exist  between  types  of  farms  in  regard  to 
the  proportions  that  fall  into  the  various  economic  classes.  The 
number  of  each  type  of  commercial  farm  by  economic  class  is 
shown  in  table  2. 

Table  2. — Number  of  Farms  in  Each  Type  of  Farm  by  EcO' 
nomic  Class,  for  the  United  States:  1954 


Total 

Economic  class  of  farm 

I 

II 

III 

IV 

V 

VI 

All     commercial 
farms 

3,327,889 
537,  '.174 
525.  403 
307,  733 
32,581 

82,096 

548.  707 
154,  251 

694,888 

80,039 
113,  107 
203,843 
37,  057 

134,064 

21.995 
15.239 
5,  585 
3,751 

10,  675 
11.698 
13,  137 

39,835 

3,784 
592 

3,  202 
4,481 

448,  847 
110,597 
25,  5N5 
15,  414 

15,  330 

76.083 
28,  554 

121,  287 

9,955 
7,  156 

28.  578 
5,828 

706,852 
Im,  337 
47,013 
47,706 
5,094 

16,367 

156,  506 
28,  582 

152,  413 

14,417 
16,414 

56,  470 
5,533 

S12, 108 
129.042 
116,  163 
114,222 
6,384 

16,  876 

153.690 
27,605 

143,  072 

20,  255 

59|  015 
7,122 

763,515 

82.  789 

1S7.  228 

117.  121 

6,495 

I02!  836 
28,  923 

137,  490 

21,  054 

13.804 
41,  565 
8,357 

462.  503 

Other  field-crop 

67.  685 

Livestock    other    than 
dairy  and  poultry 

General: 
Primarily  crop 

Primarily  livestock 
Crop  ami  livestock   . 

100,791 

10,  574 

6.  569 
1  1,  923 

Class  I  farms  (farms  with  a  total  value  of  farm  products  sold  of 
$25,000  or  more)  are  not  numerous,  nationally.  They  numbered 
134,064  in  1054  and  comprised  only  4  percent  of  the  commercial 
farm  numbers.  Most  of  the  Class  I  farms  are  found  among  types 
of  farms  that  are  numerically  important.  Livestock  farms,  for 
example,  account  for  21  percent  of  all  commercial  farms.  About 
30  percent  of  the  Class  I  farms  are  of  this  type.  Cash-grain  and 
cotton  farms,  also  numerous  nationally,  accounted  for  16  percent 
and  1 1  percent,  respectively  of  the  Class  I  farms.  Of  these  types, 
however,  Class  I  farms  comprise  a  small  proportion  of  the  number 
of  farms.  Only  3  percent  of  the  cotton  farms,  and  4  percent  of  the 
cash-grain  farms  were  classified  in  Class  I. 

In  some  types  of  farming,  farms  with  sales  of  $25,000  or  more 
account  for  a  sizable  proportion  of  the  farms.  These  are  primarily 
highly  specialized  types  that  are  not  numerous  nationally.  Fruit- 
and-nut  farms  accounted  for  less  than  3  percent  of  the  commercial 
farms,  but  among  farms  of  this  type  13  percent  were  classified  as 
Class  I.  More  than  11  percent  of  the  vegetable  farms  and  8 
percent  of  the  poultry  farms  had  sales  of  $25,000  or  more. 

Classes  II,  III,  and  IV  are  often  referred  to  as  the  family-size 
farms.  The  value  of  farm  products  sold  ranges  from  a  lower  limit 
of  $2,500  on  Class  IV  farms  to  an  upper  limit  of  $25,000  on  Class  II 
farms.  About  three-fifths  of  all  commercial  farms  fall  in  these 
classes.  But  farms  in  these  economic  classes  are  much  more 
typical  of  some  types  of  farming  than  others. 

Economic  Classes  II,  III,  and  IV  comprised  about  75  percent  of 
the  total  number  of  cash-grain  farms,  and  only  slightly  less  of  the 
dairy  farms  and  general  farms.  Substantially  more  than  half  of 
the  farms  in  each  of  the  other  types  were  in  these  economic  classes 
with  the  exception  of  cotton  farms,  other  field-crop  farms,  and 
vegetable  farms.      More  than  60  percent  of  the  cotton  farms,  50 


percent  of  the  other  field-crop  farms,  and  40  percent  of  the  vege- 
table farms  fell  in  Classes  V  and  VI  (gross  farm  sales  of  less  than 
$2,500).  These  farms  are  often  referred  to  as  "low-production" 
or  "low-income"  farms. 

Table  3. — Percent  Distribution  of  Farms  in  Each  Type  of 
Farm  by  Economic  Class,  for  the  United  States:  1954 


Type  of  farm 

Total 

Economic  class  of  farm 

I 

II 

III 

IV 

V 

VI 

100.0 

100!  0 
100.0 
100.0 

100.0 
100  0 
100.0 

100.0 

100.0 
100.0 
100.0 
100.0 

4.0 
4.1 
2.9 
1.5 
11.5 

13.0 

2  1 

5.7 

4.7 
0.9 
1.6 

12   1 

13.  5 
20.6 

4^2 
13.8 

18.7 
13.9 
18.5 

17.5 

12.4 
11.3 
14.0 
15.7 

21.2 
29.8 
8.9 
13.0 
15.6 

19.9 

28.5 
18.5 

21.9 

18.0 
26.0 
27.7 
14.9 

24.4 

24.0 
22.1 
31.1 
19.6 

20.6 

17!  9 

20.6 

25.3 
29.5 
29.0 
19.2 

22.9 
15.4 

35.6 
31    s 
19.9 

19.3 
18.7 
18.8 

19.8 

26.3 
21.8 
20.4 
22.6 

13.9 
6.2 
25.5 
18.4 
19.6 

8.5 
8.7 
17.8 

14.5 
13.2 

Livestock    other    than    dairy    and 

General: 

7.3 
15.5 

Table  4. — Percent  Distribution  of  Farms  in  Each  Economic 
Class,  by  Type  of  Farm,  for  the  United  States:  1954 


Type  of  farm 

Total 

Economic  class  of  farm 

I 

II 

III 

IV 

V 

VI 

100.0 
16.2 
15.8 
11.0 
1.0 

2.5 
16.5 
4.6 

20.9 

2.4 
1.9 
6.1 
1.1 

100.0 

16.4 
11.4 
4.2 
2.8 

8.0 

8  7 
9.8 

29.7 

2.8 
0.4 
2.5 
3.3 

100.0 
24.6 
5.7 

L0 

3.4 

17.0 
6.4 

27.0 

2.2 
1.6 
6.4 
1.3 

100.0 
22.7 
6.7 
6.7 
0.7 

2.3 

22.1 
4.0 

21.6 

2.0 
2.3 
8.0 

0.8 

100.0 
15.9 
14.3 
14.1 
0.8 

2.1 

18.9 
3.4 

17.6 

2.5 
2.3 
7.3 
0.9 

100.0 
10.8 
24.5 
15.3 
0.9 

2.1 
13.5 

18.0 

2.8 
1.8 
5.4 
1.1 

100.0 
7.2 
29.0 
14.6 

Cash-Rrain_. 

10.4 
5.9 

21.8 
2.3 

Livestock    other    than    dairy    and 

General: 

Primarily  crop 

1.2 

To  summarize,  cash-grain  farms,  dairy  farms,  livestock  farms, 
and  general  farms  are  characterized  by  a  small  proportion  of  very 
large  farms  or  of  extremely  small  farms,  when  measured  in  terms 
of  gross  sales.  Poultry  farms,  fruit-and-nut  farms,  and  vegetable 
farms  have  a  relatively  high  proportion  of  operations  which  grossed 
$25,000  or  more  in  1954  and  somewhat  fewer  farms  in  the  medium- 
size  groups.  Vegetable  and  poultry  farms  are  also  characterized 
by  a  fairly  high  proportion  of  small  operations  which  had  gross 
sales  of  less  than  $2,500.  Relatively  few  fruit-and-nut  farms 
produce  at  this  small  volume  of  business. 

Few  of  the  cotton  and  other  field-crop  farms  sold  as  much  as 
$25,000  of  farm  products.  More  than  half  sold  less  than  $2,500  of 
farm  products.  More  than  two-fifths  of  all  Class  V  and  Class  VI 
farms  were  of  these  two  types. 


IS 


FARMERS  AND  FARM  PRODUCTION 


CHANGES  IN  THE  STRUCTURE  OF  COMMERCIAL  FARMING 


CHANGES  AFFECT  FARMERS  DIFFERENTLY 

Agriculture  is  confronted  with  many  problems  of  production 
and  is  undergoing  basic  adjustments.  These  problems,  and  the 
kinds  of  adjustments  that  may  be  needed,  vary  considerably  by 
types  and  sizes  of  farms. 

Changes  that  have  affected  agriculture  have  had  different 
impacts  upon  the  several  types  and  sizes  of  farms.  This  is  true 
for  new  developments  in  farm-production  practices,  changes  in 
demand,  and  prices  of  products,  as  well  as  for  the  more  general 
changes. 

Improved  techniques  designed  to  increase  yields  and  decrease 
labor  needs  in  farming  have  varied  in  their  adaptability  to  different 
crop  and  livestock  enterprises  and  different  sizes  of  farms.  Differ- 
ential rates  of  progress  have  been  characteristic  in  the  invention 
of  machinery  to  mechanize  completely  the  production  of  the 
major  cash  crops.  Notable  examples  are  the  cash  grains,  which 
for  many  years  have  been  grown  and  harvested  almost  entirely 
with  machinery;  and  tobacco,  which  still  requires  a  great  deal 
of  hand  labor,  particularly  at  harvest.  Mechanization  has  been 
more  feasible  for  farmers  on  larger  acreage  units  and  for  those 
with  land  that  is  fairly  level  and  in  sizable  tracts.  Because  of 
the  high  capital  requirements,  the  financial  and  credit  positions 
of  farmers  have  also  been  important  factors  bearing  on  the  rate 
of  mechanization. 

Farmers  have  not  benefited  equally  even  in  the  more  simple 
practices  of  increasing  yields.  The  results  from  use  of  com- 
mercial fertilizer,  which  have  been  so  noticeable  in  humid  eastern 
areas,  have  not  proven  as  effective  in  areas  where  rainfall  is  more 
limited.  Crop  yields  have  been  increased  by  using  a  wide  variety 
of  improved  plants  and  seeds,  but  only  a  few  crops  have  had 
such  spectacular  success  as  hybrid  corn,  which  has  affected  the 
farmers  in  the  Corn  Belt,  primarily. 

More  general  changes,  that  have  originated  in  the  economic 
growth  of  the  Nation,  have  also  had  different  impact  upon  the 
various  sectors  of  agriculture.  With  increasing  concentration 
of  population  in  cities,  farmers  have  needed  to  produce  the 
products  demanded  by  urban  tastes  and  customs.  Substitutions 
of  commodities  have  taken  place.  Consumers  are  buying  less 
of  the  starchy  foods  in  the  form  of  bread,  flour,  potatoes,  and 
rice,  and  are  buying  more  meats,  milk,  eggs,  and  fresh  vegetables. 
Vegetable  oils  have  increased  in  demand  for  both  household  and 
industrial  uses. 

Rapid  transportation  and  new  processes  for  freezing  foods  have 
changed  the  locational  advantages  of  farmers.  These  develop- 
ments have  enabled  some  farmers  who  are  far  from  population 
centers  to  compete  for  what  were  formerly  local  markets.  The 
development  and  production  of  synthetic  fibers,  the  decline  in 
foreign  markets,  and  the  competition  of  foreign  agricultural 
producers,  each  has  a  distinct  impact  upon  the  structure  of 
American  agriculture. 

Commercial  farms  have  become  fewer  but  they  are  much  larger 
when  measured  by  either  the  volume  of  farm  sales  or  the  acres 
of  land  in  farms.  The  larger  farms  have  become  more  numerous 
and  there  are  fewer  small  farms.  At  the  same  time,  there  have 
been  shifts  in  farming  from  one  type  to  another.  Along  with 
the  reduction  in  the  number  of  commercial  farms,  most  types  of 
farms  have  decreased  in  actual  number,  but  at  different  rates. 
Some  types  have  increased  as  a  proportion  of  the  commercial 
farms.  The  changing  structure  is  also  reflected  in  adjustments 
made  in  the  composition  and  use  of  farm  resources. 


Changes  in  agriculture  are  gradual.  Most  of  the  comparisons 
of  changes,  which  follow,  are  based  upon  the  Censuses  of  1950 
and  1954.  The  time  period  is  too  short  to  permit  isolation 
of  long-run  trends  or  to  warrant  conclusions  regarding  the  implica- 
tions of  these  changes.  Some  of  the  changes  that  have  occurred 
between  1950  and  1954  are  thought  to  be  illustrative  of  basic 
and  long-run  adjustments  that  are  being  made.  Others  may 
reflect  only  short-run  variations  that  resulted  from  conditions 
peculiar  to  one  or  the  other  years  under  consideration. 

The  Censuses  of  1950  and  1954  are  selected  as  the  basis  of  these 
comparisons  because  of  the  comparability  of  classifications  used. 
Both  Censuses  provide  data  on  the  characteristics  of  farms  grouped 
by  economic  class  and  by  type  of  farm.  The  criteria  used  by 
the  two  Censuses  for  determining  economic  class  and  type  of 
farm  were  identical.  These  classifications  permit  a  more  detailed 
examination  of  changes  in  commercial  agriculture  than  has  been 
possible  previously. 

CHANGES  BY  ECONOMIC  CLASSES 

Between  1950  and  1954  the  number  of  commercial  farms 
decreased  by  378,523,  a  decrease  of  approximately  10  percent. 
The  number  of  Class  I  farms  increased  by  30,833.  This  represents 
an  increase  of  more  than  a  fourth  in  the  number  of  these  large 
operations.  As  a  proportion  of  the  total  commercial  farms, 
however,  Class  I  farms  comprised  less  than  3  percent  in  1950  and 
only  4  percent  in  1954.     (See  table  5.) 


Table  5. — Changes  in  Number  and  Percent  Distribution  of 
Commercial  Farms,  by  Economic  Class,  for  the  United 
States:  1950  to  1954 


Economic  class  of  farm 

Number 

Increase   or   de- 
crease  (-)  from 
1950  to  1954 

Percent  of 
farms 

1950 

1954 

Number 

Percent 

1949 

1954 

Commercial  farms 

3,  706, 412 
103,  231 
381,  151 
721,  211 
SN2.3II2 
901,316 
717,201 

').  1127,  8.S9 

134,064 

448,847 

Sli  1IW 
703.515 
462,  503 

-378, 523 

30,  833 

-U.M) 
-70, 194 
-137,801 
-254,698 

-10.2 
29.9 
17.8 
-2.0 
-8.0 
-16.3 
-34.1 

100.0 
2.8 
10.4 
19.6 
23.8 
24.2 
19.1 

100.0 
4.0 

21.2 

24.4 

22.9 

The  number  of  farms  in  Class  II  increased  by  63,000 — an 
increase  of  16  percent.  Farms  in  this  class  comprised  about 
13  percent  of  the  commercial  farms  in  1954,  compared  with  10 
percent  in  1950. 

Farms  in  the  smaller  economic  classes  decreased  in  number. 
This  decrease  was  relatively  small  for  Economic  Classes  III  and 
IV.  While  decreasing  in  actual  number,  farms  in  these  classes 
comprised  a  slightly  larger  proportion  of  the  commercial  farms 
in  1954  than  in  1950.  Most  of  the  reduction  in  the  number  of 
commercial  farms  was  among  the  small  farms  producing  less  than 
$2,500  of  farm  products  for  sale.  Class  V  farms  decreased  by 
132,156,  a  decrease  of  15  percent,  and  Class  VI  farms  decreased 
in  number  by  245,561,  a  decrease  of  35  percent.  These  classes, 
taken  together,  accounted  for  36  percent  of  the  commercial 
farms   in    1954   compared   with   43   percent   5   years   earlier. 


A  GENERAL  VIEW 


19 


The  average  prices  received  by  farmers  for  all  farm  products 
sold  were  at  approximately  the  same  level  in  both  1949  and  1954. 
The  economic  classifications  based  on  farm  sales  in  each  of  these 
years  are  comparable  in  terms  of  the  physical  volume  of  farm 
production  represented.  Changes  in  the  number  of  farms  by 
economic  class  between  1950  and  1954  indicate  the  substantial 
increase  in  farm  production  that  took  place.  This  alone  would 
have  been  sufficient  to  cause  many  farms  to  fall  in  larger  economic 
classes.  But  in  addition,  there  was  a  reduction  in  the  number 
of  farms  and  this  land  was  incorporated  in  the  remaining  farms 
giving  them  a  larger  acreage  base.  The  shift  to  larger  economic 
classes  was  a  combination  of  the  increase  in  production  per  acre 
and  per  animal  unit  and  the  larger  acreage  base  per  farm. 

The  increase  in  size  of  farm  is  a  part  of  technological  progress 
in  agriculture.  The  greater  use  of  farm  machinery  enables  a 
smaller  work  force  to  tend  more  acres  and  more  animal  units  and 
to  harvest  a  larger  production.  The  increase  in  farm  size  does 
not  necessarily  indicate  a  shift  toward  large-scale  farms  employing 
large  numbers  of  hired  workers.  In  fact  all  indications  are  that 
substantial  growth  took  place  on  farms  operated  primarily  with 
family  labor.  Many  of  these  farms  acquired  additional  land  in 
order  to  utilize  their  machinery  more  efficiently. 


SPECIALIZATION  IN  FARMING 

Changing  conditions  have  also  had  their  impact  upon  the  types 
of  farming — the  commodities  produced,  the  number  of  producers, 
and  the  combination  of  farm  enterprises.  A  question  of  current 
interest  relates  to  specialization  in  agriculture;  more  specifically, 
whether  or  not  recent  developments  have  encouraged  farmers  to 
specialize  in  one  or  more  enterprises  rather  than  produce  several 
different  commodities  in  more  diversified  types  of  farming. 

A  conclusive  answer  to  this  question  would  require  a  more 
detailed  analysis  than  is  given  in  this  report.  However,  some 
indication  of  probable  trends  may  be  drawn  from  changes  in  the 
number  and  proportion  of  farms  that  produced  one  or  more  of 
several  major  commodities  during  the  25-year  period  ending  in 
1954.     These  changes  are  shown  in  table  6. 

The  trend  of  the  last  25  years  indicates  that  most  major  com- 
modities are  now  produced  by  fewer  farms  and  by  a  smaller  propor- 
tion of  the  farms.     This  trend  is  much  more  pronounced  in  the 


production  of  some  commodities  than  others.  In  the  case  of 
tobacco  the  trend  is  in  the  opposite  direction. 

In  interpretation  of  these  trends  one  must  consider  recent 
developments  in  methods  of  production,  marketing  and  processing, 
changes  in  consumer  demand,  the  time  period  under  consideration, 
and  the  types  of  Government  programs  in  effect. 

One  of  the  major  pressures  for  greater  specialization  in  agricul- 
ture has  been  the  need  for  efficient  utilization  of  machinery  and 
other  capital  equipment.  Investments  in  farm  machinery  and  in 
improved  housing  and  facilities  for  livestock  and  poultry  have  not 
been  profitable  unless  the  enterprise  was  carried  on  in  sufficient 
volume.  In  order  to  gain  the  advantages  from  use  of  new  tech- 
nology, many  farmers  have  found  it  necessary  to  concentrate  on 
one  or  a  few  enterprises  rather  than  several. 

The  small  change  in  the  proportion  of  farms  producing  wheat 
is  owing  largely  to  the  time  period.  Mechanization  in  the  produc- 
tion of  small  grains  was  well  underway  prior  to  1929.  The  changes 
in  production  techniques  of  the  last  25  years  have  not  been  so 
important  as  those  that  occurred  during  the  preceding  two 
decades.  In  contrast,  mechanization  of  cotton  production  has 
been  a  more  recent  occurrence.  Its  impact  on  the  number  and 
proportion  of  farms  producing  cotton  is  apparent. 

The  increasing  number  and  proportion  of  farms  producing 
tobacco  are  attributable  to  the  lack  of  progress  in  developing 
labor-saving  equipment  to  perform  certain  crucial  operations, 
and  the  lack  of  more  profitable  alternatives  to  tobacco  for  many 
farmers  in  the  producing  areas.  Government  programs — acreage 
allotments  and  price  supports — may  have  also  contributed  to 
the  trend. 

The  increase  in  the  proportion  of  farms  selling  milk  is  in  accord 
with  the  greater  consumption  of  fluid  milk  by  a  growing 
population. 

Production  of  broilers  and  eggs  and  of  vegetables  for  sale  show 
noticeable  trends  toward  greater  specialization.  The  sale  of  eggs 
and  chickens  from  home  flocks  has  been  supplanted  by  modern 
efficient  highly  specialized  operations.  This  change  reflects  im- 
provements in  disease  control,  feeding  and  housing,  and  other 
developments  that  enable  fewer  workers  to  care  for  a  larger  number 
of  birds.  Along  with  developments  in  transportation  and  process- 
ing, vegetable  production,  which  used  to  be  centered  in  environs 
of  most  of  the  larger  cities,  has  shifted  to  areas  having  other  natural 
advantages. 


-Number  and  Proportion  of  Farms  Having  Production  or  Sales  of  Specified  Commodities,  for  the  United  States  by 
Specified  Years:  1929  to  1954 


1929 

1939 

1949 

1954 

Item 

Number  of 

Percent  of 
all  farms 

Number  of 
farms 

Percent  of 
all  farms 

Number  of 
farms 

Percent  of 
all  farms 

Number  of 

Percent  of 
all  farms 

4,  597,  949 

1,  208,  368 

1,  986,  726 

432,  975 

627,  452 

893,  431 

(NA) 

3, 129,  715 

3,  872, 482 
(NA) 
(NA) 

73.1 
19.2 
31.6 
6.9 

10.0 
14.2 

(NA) 
49.8 

61.6 
(NA) 
(NA) 

4,  456,  259 

1,  385,  774 

1,589,723 

498, 348 

462,552 
953,  898 

1,  460,  383 
2,519,076 

(NA) 

2,  625,  783 
1,842,704 

73.1 
22.7 
26.1 
8.2 

7.6 
15.6 
24.0 
41.3 

(NA) 
43.1 
30.2 

3, 403, 965 

l  1, 147,  710 

1,110,876 

"531,922 

346,528 

1,  096,  650 

862,128 

1,  713, 435 

2,  420,  718 
2,982,616 
2, 097,  807 

63.2 
'  21.3 
20.6 

6.4 
20.4 
16.0 
31.8 

45.0 
55.4 
39.0 

2,  844,  369 

>J1,004,607 

864,  138 

!  513, 346 

279,606 

934, 143 

540,  556 

1,030,287 

1,  684, 531 
2,611,031 
1,423,943 

Vegetables  harvested  for  sale  other  than  Irish  potatoes  and 

Gieam  sold 

11.3 

N'A  Not  available. 

1  Totals  for  States  fur  which  data  are  available. 

'■  Inr-lu'les  sijmm-  <lui'lw:ituin  of  farina  ivj.mim-  <liiTcrent,  typos  of  wheat. 
•  InrluMi'S  -.nil if  -in  plication  of  farms  rvpoj  Mh-j.  .iitlVivnt.  types  of  tobacco . 


20 


FARMERS  AND  FARM  PRODUCTION 


CHANGES  IN  TYPE  OF  FARM 

Between  1950  and  1954  there  was  a  decrease  in  number  of  each 
type  of  farm  except  cash-grain  farms.  (See  table  7.)  Cash-grain 
farms  increased  by  more  than  100,000,  or  about  a  fourth.  The 
greatest  reduction  in  absolute  number  occurred  among  dairy 
farms  and  general  farms,  which  decreased  by  about  150,000  each. 
Among  general  farms,  those  classified  as  primarily  livestock, 
decreased  by  nearly  half.  Other  livestock  farms  and  cotton 
farms,  among  the  most  numerous  types  nationally,  decreased 
by  111,000  and  84,000,  respectively.  Fruit-and-nut  farms  and 
vegetable  farms  are  specialized  types  that  are  not  numerous 
nationally.  Fruit-and-nut  farms  remained  about  the  same  in 
number  while  vegetable  farms  decreased  by  nearly  a  third. 


Table  7- — Changes  in  Number  and  Percent  Distribution 
of  Commercial  Farms,  by  Type  of  Farm,  for  the  United 
States:  1950  to  1954 


Type  of  farm 

Number 

Increase  or  de- 
crease (— )  from 
1950  to  1954 

Percent  of 

1950 

1954 

Number 

Percent 

1950 

1954 

Commercial  farms 

Cash -'.Main 

3, 706, 412 
130,389 
609,307 
409,  421 
46,415 

82, 178 

602.093 
175,  876 

806,080 

494,  285 
84,  569 
134,  66(1 
275,  050 

50,368 

3,  327,  889 

r.:(7. 974 

307 !  733 
32,  581 

82,  096 

548,  767 
154,  251 

694,888 

347,  079 

63!  197 
203  843 

37,  057 

-378,  523 

107,585 
-83,811 
-41.688 

-13,834 

-82 
-153.326 
-21,625 

-111,192 

-147,206 
-4,  530 
-71,469 
-71,207 

-13,311 

-10.2 
.24.8 
-13.8 
-10.2 
-29.  8 

-0.1 
-25.5 
-12.3 

-13.8 

-29.8 
-5.4 
-53.1 
-25.9 

-26.4 

100. 0 
11.6 
16.4 
11.0 
1.3 

2.2 
16.2 
4.7 

21.7 

13.3 
2.3 
3.6 

7.4 

1.4 

100.  0 
16.2 

*  Ulii'!  lielil-crop 

11. I 

Livestock    other   than    dairy 

Primarily  livestock 

Crop  and  livestock 

1.9 

6.1 

Changes  in  types  of  farms  by  economic  class. — Cash-grain 
farms  were  the  only  type  that  increased  numerically  between 
1950  and  1954.  Fruit-and-nut  farms  remained  about  the  same. 
There  were  decreases  in  the  number  of  all  other  types.  Decreases 
also  occurred  among  farms  in  each  of  the  smaller  economic 
classes — -Classes  III  through  VI.  The  larger  farms,  Classes  I 
and  II,  increased  substantially. 

These  changes  in  number  have  brought  about  noticeable 
differences  in  the  size  structure  of  the  individual  type  of  farm 
(see  table.  8).  There  was  an  increase  in  the  number  of  Class  I 
farms  for  each  type.  Numerically,  this  increase  was  greatest  on 
cash-grain  farms,  an  increase  of  8,000  Class  I  farms.  This  type 
accounted  for  more  than  a  fourth  of  the  total  increase  in  Class  I 
farms. 

The  next  largest  increase  in  Class  I  farms  occurred  among 
fruit-and-nut  farms.  The  increase  of  5,000  Class  I  farms  repre- 
sented an  increase  to  twice  the  number  of  these  farms  in  1950. 
Sizable  increases  in  the  number  of  Class  I  farms  also  occurred  for 
cotton,  poultry,  and  other  livestock  farms. 

The  number  of  Class  II  farms  increased  for  most  types.  Over 
half  of  the  increase  was  for  cash-grain  farms  and  a  fourth  of  the 
increase  was  for  dairy  farms.  The  decreases  in  Class  II  farms 
were  of  relatively  minor  proportions  where  they  occurred. 

The  changes  in  the  number  of  Class  III  farms  occurred  only 
for  a  few  types.  The  decreases  were  virtually  all  for  other  live- 
stock, general  livestock,  and  general  crop  and  livestock  farms;  a 
total  decrease  of  60,000  farms.  This  was  partially  offset  by  sub- 
stantial increases  for  cash-grain  and  other  field-crop  farms. 
Changes  in  the  number  of  Class  III  farms  were  slight  for  the 
remaining  types. 


Table  8. — Changes  in  Number  of  Farms,  for  Each  Type  of 
Commercial  Farm,  by  Economic  Class,  for  the  United 
States:  1950  to  1954 

[A  minus  sign  (-)  indicates  a  decrease] 


Type  of  farm 


Increase     or     decrease, 
1950  to  1954: 

Commercial  farms 

Cash-grain 

Cotton 

Other  field-crop 

Vegetable 

Fruit-and-nut 

Dairy,. 

Poultry 

livestock  other  than 
dairy  and  poultry 

General: 
Primarily  crop. . 
Primarily     live- 
Crop     and     live- 
Miscellaneous 

1954  as  percent  of  1950: 

Commercial  farms 

Cash-grain 

Cotton 

Other  field-crop 

Vegetable 

Fruit-and-nut 

Dairy 

Poultry 

Livestock  other  than 
dairy  ami  poultry 

General: 
Primarily  crop  .. 
Primarily     live- 
stock  

Crop     and     live- 
stock  

Miscellaneous 


-13,831 
-  :,3,320 

111,192 

-4,  530 
-71,469 
-71,  207 


Economic  class  of  farm 


11,  359 
32.  593 
2,041 
KI.H'.lll 
-1,649 


-2.(153 
-20,215 
-6,425 

-33,  508 


1,184 
-23,244 

-  18,  948 


-  1.071 
-30.581 
-14,110 


-18.932 
-23,462 


-25  1.098 
-3,  710 
-104,314 

-28,932 

-5,291 
-4,568 

-15,593 
-11.757 


Decreases  in  the  number  of  Class  IV  farms  took  place  for  all 
types  except  cash-grain  and  cotton  farms.  The  bulk  of  the  de- 
crease was  for  dairy  farms  and  the  livestock  types  listed  in  the 
preceding  paragraph.  Class  IV  cash-grain  and  cotton  farms  in- 
creased by  a  fifth  and  a  fourth,  respectively. 

With  the  exception  of  cash-grain  farms,  the  number  of  Class  V 
farms  decreased  substantially  for  each  type.  The  net  decrease  of 
132,000  was  a  decrease  of  15  percent  from  the  number  in  1950. 
The  greatest  proportionate  decrease  was  for  general  livestock 
farms,  a  decrease  of  60  percent. 

There  was  a  decrease  of  246,000  in  Class  VI  farms.  The  number 
of  these  small  farms  declined  for  each  type  of  farm.  The  greatest 
numerical  decrease  was  for  cotton  farms,  a  decrease  of  104,000. 
The  greatest  proportionate  decrease  was  for  general  livestock  ar.d 
general  crop  and  livestock  farms.  On  these  types  the  number  of 
Class  VI  farms  declined  to  only  a  third  their  number  in  1950. 

Increases  and  decreases  in  some  types  of  farms  are  closely 
related  to  changes  in  relative  prices  received  by  farmers  for 
different  commodities,  and  changes  in  cost-price  relationships 
that  affect  alternative  enterprises  on  the  farm.  Type  of  farm 
was  based  upon  sales  of  farm  products  in  the  particular  year. 
Farms  having  substantial  sales  from  two  or  more  commodities 
(or  commodity  groups)  may  have  been  classified  in  some  cases 
as  one  type  in  1950  and  another  type  in  1954.  This  shifting 
between  types  probably  accounts  for  a  considerable  part  of  the 
increase  in  cash-grain  farms  and  the  decrease  in  livestock  farms 
and  general  farms  between  1950  and  1954. 

Along  with  the  decrease  in  total  commercial  farm  numbers, 
farms  of  most  types  have  declined  in  number.  But  within  the 
overall  decrease  there  have  been  differences  in  the  changes  geo- 
graphically. 


A  GENERAL  VIEW 


21 


Geographic  changes  in  type  and  economic  class. — The  decline 
in  the  number  of  the  smaller  economic  classes  of  farms,  the  in- 
crease in  the  larger  classes,  and  the  overall  reduction  in  the  total 
number  of  commercial  farms  between  1950  and  1954,  is  but  a 
continuation  of  the  trend  in  recent  decades.  The  changes  in  the 
number  of  farms  by  type  and  their  size  distribution,  however,  is 
primarily  useful  in  a  description  of  the  current  5-year  period 
rather  than  for  use  in  plotting  long-run  trends  or  making  future 
projections.  Changes  in  the  number  of  farms  by  type  as  well 
as  by  economic  class  include  shifts  from  one  type  or  class  into 
another. 

The  maps  on  the  following  pages  show  the  geographic  location 
of  the  changes  in  economic  classes  and  types  of  farms.  These 
maps  show  a  fairly  high  degree  of  correlation  in  some  areas 
between  decreases  in  some  types  and  classes  of  farms  and  as- 
sociated increases  in  other  types  and  classes.  Because  of  the 
overall  decline  in  the  number  of  commercial  farms,  however,  it 
is  not  always  possible  to  distinguish  between  the  shifts  between 
classes  and  types  and  the  complete  disappearance  of  farms  of 
any  given  type  and  class. 

The  increase  in  cash-grain  farms  between  1950  and  1954  was 
highly  concentrated  in  the  feed-grain  sections  of  Indiana  and 
Ohio,  southeastern  Illinois,  north-central  Iowa,  and  south-central 
Minnesota.  In  the  wheat-producing  areas  further  west,  increases 
in  cash-grain  farms  occurred  in  central  Kansas  and  other  scattered 
areas. 

Increases  also  took  place  on  the  Delmarva  Peninsula  largely 
because  of  an  increased  production  of  soybeans.  For  the  most 
part,  increases  in  cash-grain  farms  in  the  wheat  areas  were  com- 
pensated by  decreases  in  adjoining  areas.  The  acreage  in  wheat 
declined  throughout  the  Plains.  Even  in  Kansas,  where  increases 
in  cash-grain  farms  occurred,  the  acreage  of  wheat  declined  while 
that  of  grain  sorghums  increased. 

Increases  in  cash-grain  farms  are  closely  associated  with  de- 
creases that  occurred  in  general  farms  (primarily  livestock  and 
primarily  crop  and  livestock)  and  other  livestock  farms.  The 
increase  in  cash-grain  farms  in  each  of  the  midwestern  and  Plains 
areas  coincided  with  decreases  in  the  number  of  livestock  and 
general  farms.  Furthermore,  the  increases  in  the  former  and 
decreases  in  the  latter  types  are  of  approximately  the  same  magni- 
tude. 

The  shift  from  livestock  and  general  to  cash-grain  farms  be- 
tween 1950  and  1954  is  due  largely  to  changes  in  the  relative  prices 
of  grains  and  livestock.  The  prices  farmers  received  for  feed 
grains  were  higher  relative  to  livestock  prices  in  1949  than  in  1954. 
The  table  below  shows  the  index  of  prices  received  by  farmers  for 
feed  grains  and  livestock  for  the  years  1949  to  1954.  In  order  to 
show  the  relative  change  between  1949  and  1954,  the  index  has 
been  computed  with  1949  equal  to  100. 


Year 

Index  of  prices  received  by 
farmers  (1949=100) 

Feed  grains 
and  hay 

animals 

100 
109 
128 

US 
116 

100 

In  areas  affected  by  the  shift  from  general  and  livestock  to 
cash-grain  farms,  feed  grains  and  livestock  are  usually  grown  on 
the  same  farms,  and  income  is  derived  from  sales  of  both  products. 
A  change  in  price  of  one  relative  to  the  other  may  change  the 
Census  classification  of  these  farms  even  though  the  farm  organi- 
zation remains  the  same.  Also,  during  a  period  in  which  prices 
for  feed  grains  are  high  relative  to  prices  for  livestock,  more  of 
the  grain  is  sold,  resulting  first  in  animals  being  marketed  at 
lighter  weights,  followed  by  curtailment  of  the  production  of 
meat  animals  by  reduction  in  breeding  stock.  During  this  period 
sales  of  corn  and  soybeans  increased  substantially. 

Decreases  in  livestock  and  general  farms  in  Kentucky  and 
Tennessee  are  related  to  increases  in  other  field-crop  farms  and, 
in  western  Kentucky,  to  a  slight  increase  in  cash-grain  farms. 
While  the  number  of  farms  reporting  sales  of  tobacco  decreased 
slightly  between  1949  and  1954,  yields  were  higher  in  the  latter 
year  and  also  the  value  of  tobacco  sold.  This,  along  with  lower 
prices  for  livestock,  meant  that  many  of  the  farms  that  were 
classified  as  livestock  and  general  in  1950,  were  classified  in  the 
other  field-crop  category  in  1954. 

Decreases  in  livestock  and  general  farms  in  these  States  are  also 
related  to  the  reduction  in  the  number  of  commercial  farms.  A 
high  proportion  of  the  livestock  and  general  farms  were  in  the 
smaller  economic  classes  of  farms  that  have  been  disappearing 
rapidly  in  recent  decades. 

The  other  field-crop  farms  (primarily  tobacco  and  peanut  farms) 
decreased  in  all  areas,  except  for  the  increases  in  Kentucky  and 
Tennessee.  These  decreases  are  closely  related  to  the  large 
reduction  in  Class  V  and  VI  farms  in  the  flue-cured  tobacco  and 
peanut  areas  of  Virginia,  the  Carolinas,  Georgia,  and  Alabama. 
In  the  Georgia- Alabama  area  part  of  the  decreases  represent  shifts 
from  tobacco  and  peanuts  to  cotton,  livestock,  and  general  types 
of  farming. 

In  central  Louisiana  the  decrease  in  other  field-crop  farms 
represents  a  decline  in  sugarcane  farms.  There  was  a  sharp 
decrease  in  the  acreage  and  yield  as  well  as  the  number  of  farmers 
growing  sugarcane.  These  decreases  were  compensated  by  an 
almost  identical  increase  in  cotton  farms. 

The  number  of  cotton  farms  decreased  throughout  most  of  the 
old  Cotton  Belt,  extending  from  the  Carolinas  westward  to  east 
Texas.  These  decreases  are  closely  related  to  decreases  in  Class  VI 
farms.  The  number  of  these  small  cotton  farms  decreased  by- 
more  than  100,000.  In  the  old  Cotton  Belt,  however,  increases 
in  cotton  farms  occurred  in  the  Coastal  Plains  of  the  Carolinas, 
the  southern  Georgia-Alabama  and  the  central  Louisiana  areas 
discussed  previously,  and  throughout  central  and  southern 
Mississippi.  In  Mississippi,  the  increase  in  cotton  farms  was 
compensated  by  decreases  in  livestock  and  general  farms,  this 
shift  being  due  primarily  to  differences  in  yields  and  prices  in 
respect  to  cotton  and  livestock,  between  1949  and  1954. 

Cotton  farms  increased  in  number  in  the  western  areas,  par- 
ticularly in  the  High  Plains  area  of  northwest  Texas.  There  the 
increased  numbers  of  cotton  farms  are  associated  with  an  increase 
in  irrigation. 

The  number  of  dairy  farms  decreased  throughout  the  North- 
east and  Lake  Dairy  areas.  There  was  some  shifting  of  type 
from  dairy  to  cash-grain  farms  in  the  cash-grain  dairy  transition 
areas.  For  the  most  part,  however,  the  decrease  in  dairy  farms 
is  related  to  fewer  farms,  particularly  in  Economic  Classes  IV 
and  V  and  the  combination  of  farms  into  larger  units. 


22 


FARMERS  AND  FARM  PRODUCTION 


Dairy  farms  have  a  widespread  distribution  over  the  country. 
In  addition  to  the  major  dairy  regions  mentioned,  there  are 
numerous  smaller  areas  of  concentration  around  many  of  the 
larger  population  centers.  Many  of  these  so-called  milksheds 
show  increases  in  the  number  of  dairy  farms  whereas  outside  of 
these  special  areas,  the  number  has  declined. 


<kii-_                  COTTON  FARMS-INCREASE  AND  DECREASE 

K#             Tr-—^.                             1N  NUMBER.  1950-1954 

\ 

U'JiTED  STATES  NET  DECREA    l       V     /~-, 

The  5-year  period  ending  in  1954  saw  poultry  farming  becom- 
ing increasingly  specialized  and  highly  concentrated  in  specific 
localities.  The  greatest  increases  occurred  in  the  Piedmont  of 
North  Carolina,  Georgia,  and  Alabama,  in  central  Arkansas, 
and  east  Texas.  Sizable  decreases  in  poultry  farms  took  place 
in  both  the  Pacific  Coast  and  Middle  Atlantic  areas. 


VEGETABLE   FARMS  -  INCREASE  AND  DECREASE 


Kte--^            FRU1T-AND 

UNITED  STATES  NET  DECREASE       V 
OR  LESS  THAN  005  PERCENT       . 

-NUT  FARMS 

-  INCREASE  AND  DECREASE 

ER.  1950-1954 

t. 

VVW- -                   DAIRY  FARMS-  INCREASE  AND  DECREASE 

YV  ^                IN  NUMBER- 195° " l954 

r\ 

/~""~>~-/Lv    '7            i['-''    ■' 

.  ^YJtk*^ 

\*  \           ■  IhrI  ••'  : 

m 

Vi      \        /.-          ,              ■      •.-.;,• 

— P- ^-tP^/7" 

v^ir 

UM1TED  STATES  NET  DECREASE       V     /— , 

53.330  OR  83  PERCENT                           \ 

''!%!££££ 

„,,-,».,,,,  C~^T 

UPHooXTa 

•■■■«•■«■" 

A  GENERAL  VIEW 


23 


iJtaS-^             POULTRY  FARMS  -  INCREASE  AND  DECREASE 

PJ       — 7T— -—                    IN  WJMBQ'-  ra5° ' l954                                                   /*~\ 

V/MV 

^"^^^P^v 

\          JT            |  DOT- 25  INCREASE                   \      \ 

FigureI32. 


Most  of  the  fruit-and-nut  farms  are  located  on  the  Pacific 
Coast  and  the  Florida  peninsula.  The  significant  change  in  the 
number  of  these  farms  was  the  decrease  in  the  Los  Angeles  area 
of  Southern  California  and  the  increase  in  central  Florida.  The 
decrease  in  the  number  of  fruit-and-nut  farms  in  Southern  Cali- 
fornia was  probably  due  to  the  combining  of  farms  into  larger 
production  units.  The  acreage  in  fruit  and  nut  trees,  as  well  as 
the  production,  remained  about  the  same,  but  was  distributed 
among  fewer  farmers.  In  central  Florida  the  land  in  fruit  or- 
chards, groves,  vineyards,  and  planted  nut  trees,  increased  by 
more  than  a  third.  This  is  one  of  the  few  areas  in  which  the 
total  number  of  farms  increased  between  1950  and  1954. 

The  number  of  vegetable  farms  decreased  by  nearly  a  third 
between  1950  and  1954.  This  decrease  was  fairly  general  in  most 
areas.  Because  of  the  small  number  of  vegetable  farms  and 
their  geographic  dispersion,  no  attempt  is  made  here  to  indicate 
the  relation  of  these  decreases  to  changes  in  other  types  of  farms. 
The  number  of  vegetable  farms  decreased  in  each  economic  class 
except  Class  I. 

Along  with  changes  in  types  of  farms  there  were  notable  changes 
in  the  geographic  distribution  of  the  economic  classes  of  farms. 
As  mentioned,  there  was  an  increase  in  the  number  of  Class  I 
farms  for  each  type  of  farm.     These  increases  in  Class  I  farms 


•GENERAL  FARMS-  INCREASE  AND  DECREASE 


were  mostly  confined  to  specific  areas.  The  area  of  greatest  in- 
crease was  in  northern  Iowa,  Illinois,  and  Indiana.  Here  they 
are  associated  closely  with  the  increase  in  cash-grain  farms. 
From  the  areas  shown  on  the  map  it  is  apparent  that  most  of  the 
increases  in  Class  I  cash-grain  farms  were  among  those  with  a 
major  source  of  income  from  sales  of  corn  and  soybeans  rather 
than  of  wheat.  In  the  wheat  areas,  increases  in  Class  I  farms 
were  confined  mainly  to  the  spring-wheat  area  of  Montana  and 
the  white-wheat  area  of  Washington. 

There  was  an  increase  in  Class  I  cotton  farms  in  the  Missis- 
sippi Delta  and  the  High  Plains  of  Texas.  In  the  Mississippi 
Delta  the  increase  was  due  largely  to  a  reduction  in  the  number 
of  cropper  farms.  Part  of  the  increase  represents  cotton  farms, 
formerly  operated  as  multiple  units,  which  decreased  the  number 
of  croppers  and  reorganized  production  to  use  hired  labor  in 
mechanized  operations. 

Increases  in  the  High  Plains  of  Texas  resulted  from  increased 
production  from  irrigated  acreages.  The  irrigated  land  in  cotton 
farms  nearly  doubled  between  1950  and  1954.  Despite  a  sharp 
decrease  in  the  acreage,  the  production  increased  by  nearly  a 
third.  The  number  of  cotton  farms  did  not  change  appreciably 
but  more  of  them  were  classified  in  the  larger  economic  classes. 

Increases  in  Class  I  farms  in  other  areas  are  associated  with 
poultry  farms,  fruit-and-nut  farms,  and  a  mixture  of  types  in  the 
Pacific  Coast  States;  fruit-and-nut  farms  in  central  Florida;  and 
cash-grain  (rice)  farms  in  southern  Louisiana. 

Decreases  in  the  number  of  Class  I  farms  were  distributed 
fairly  generally  over  the  United  States.  These  were  more 
noticeable,  however,  among  cash-grain  and  general  farms  in  the 
Plains  area  extending  from  Texas  to  Nebraska. 

Changes  in  the  geographic  distribution  of  farms  in  Economic 
Classes  II  through  VI  are  not  discussed  separately  except  as 
mentioned  previously  in  relation  to  changes  in  types  of  farms. 
In  general,  most  areas  that  show  an  increase  in  the  larger  economic 
classes  show  a  corresponding  decrease  in  the  smaller  economic 
classes.  These  changes  are  related  to  the  combinations  of  small 
farms  into  larger  units  and  to  continued  increases  in  production 
that  have  resulted  from  application  of  better  farming  practices. 
Increases  in  the  number  of  farms  in  the  smaller  economic  classes 
in  specific  localities  are  probably  due  largely  to  abnormalities  in 
production  in  1954.  Sales  may  have  been  below  normal  because 
of  poor  yields  in  that  particular  year. 


24 


FARMERS  AND  FARM  PRODUCTION 


!U^_         ECONOMIC  CLASS  I  FARMS* -INCREASE  AND  DECREASE 

|^»     i/^^T-p— -___                              IN  NUMBER.  19501954 

\?Vh— i~ii 

I0OT-SB  INCREASE            \'    \ 

UNITED  STATES  NET  INCREASE  V     ,—y                       'i 

ECONOMIC  CLASS  III  FARMS '-INCREASE  AND  DECREASE 
H954 


CHANGES  IN  SIZE  OF  ACREAGE 

In  terms  of  acreage,  commercial  farms  are  becoming  both  larger 
and  smaller.  Farms  under  10  acres  and  farms  with  more  than  200 
acres  have  increased  in  number.  (See  table  9.)  Those  in  the 
size  groups  between  10  acres  and  200  acres  have  decreased. 
Farms  in  these  size  groups,  however,  comprise  more  than  85 
percent  of  the  commercial  farms. 


N£ 

ECONOMIC  CLASS  IV  FARMS'-INCREASE  AND  DECREASE 

^~~f7— — __^                     IN  NUMBER,  1950-1954 

1    ^WS^^;^i 

(% 

~^4~£l ' 

. ,,";r--  \:ilaz-& 

"*:       \ 

■    H 

V*      /  "' 

4-A  -mM 

UNITED     STATES    NET    DECREASE 
70.35T0R   6.0  PERCENT 

sJ.W^  ECONOMIC   CLASS  V  FARMS'-INCREASE  AND    DECREASE 


The  greatest  rate  of  decrease  among  commercial  farms  came  in 
the  acreage-size  group  between  10  and  100  acres.  Farms  of  this 
size  which  account  for  nearly  two-fifths  of  all  commercial  farms, 
decreased  in  number  by  nearly  a  fifth  between  1950  and  1954. 
Farms  between  100  and  220  acres  comprise  nearly  a  third  of  the 
commercial  farms.  These  decreased  in  number  by  about  10 
percent,  or  about  the  same  rate  as  the  overall  decrease  in  com- 
mercial farms. 


A  GENERAL  VIEW 


25 


Table  9. — Changes  in  Number  of  Farms  by  Size  and 
Percent  Distribution  of  Commercial  Farms  by  Size,  for 
the  United  States:  1950  to  1954 


Acreage  size 

Number 

Increase  or  de- 
crease (-)  from 
1950  to  1954 

Percent  of 

I960 

1954 

Number 

Percent 

1950 

1954 

Commercial  farms 

3,706.412 
136.  835 
7112,  320 
710, 876 

1,162.419 

042, 01S 
174,  380 
117,568 

3,  327.  889 
145,  4(K) 
022,  921 
580,660 

1,026,664 
042.  333 
182,  5a  1 
127,  361 

-378,  523 
8.565 

-139.405 
-130,216 

-135,755 

315 

8,170 

9,803 

-10.2 

6.3 
-18.3 
-18.3 

-11.7 
0.5 
4.7 
8.3 

100.0 
3.7 
20 .6 
19.2 

31.3 
17.3 

3^2 

100.0 

100  In  219  acres 

30.9 

Farms  of  less  than  10  acres  are  not  numerous  in  commercial 
agriculture.  They  are  much  more  common  in  the  noncommercial 
farming  sector  where  many  part-time  and  residential  farmers  have 
small  acreages.  Of  the  484,000  farms  that  are  under  10  acres,  70 
percent  (339,000)  were  classified  as  part-time  or  residential  farms. 
Among  commercial  farmers,  less  than  5  percent  (145,000)  had 
farms  of  less  than  10  acres.  These  farms  increased  in  number  by  6 
percent  during  a  period  in  which  commercial  farms  as  a  group 
declined  by  10  percent. 

The  increase  in  the  number  of  farms  in  the  larger  acreage  size 
groups  between  1950  and  1954  is  but  a  continuation  of  a  trend 
toward  larger  acreage  units.  Farms  between  220  and  500  acres 
remained  about  the  same  numerically,  but  increased  as  a  propor- 
tion of  the  commercial  farms.  These  farms  comprised  a  fifth  of 
all  commercial  farms  in  1954.  Farms  with  more  than  500  acres 
account  for  less  than  10  percent  of  all  farms.  These  farms  in- 
creased numerically  by  18,000.  The  greatest  increase  came 
among  farms  of  1,000  acres  and  more — an  increase  of  8  percent. 

Change  in  acreage  by  economic  class. — There  was  a  substantial 
increase  in  the  number  of  larger  farms  between  1949  and  1954  as 
measured  by  gross  sales  of  farm  products.  Also,  the  larger 
acreage  units  increased  in  number.  These  parallel  increases  in 
size,  measured  by  both  volume  of  market  sales  and  acreage, 
portray  a  much  closer  relationship  between  the  two  measures  of 
size  than  actually  exists. 

The  increase  in  the  number  of  Class  I  farms  between  1949  and 
1954  was  accompanied  by  increases  in  each  of  the  acreage  size 
groups  (see  table  10).  There  was  an  increase  of  nearly  a  fifth 
even  in  the  few  small  units  of  less  than  10  acres  that  sold  farm 
products  valued  at  $25,000  or  more.  The  bulk  of  the  increase  in 
the  number  of  Class  I  farms  was  among  farms  of  less  than  500 
acres.  The  greatest  proportionate  increase  was  among  farms  of 
100  to  219  acres.  There  was  an  increase  of  60  percent  in  the 
number  of  farms  in  this  acreage-size  group  that  grossed  $25,000  or 
more  from  sales  of  farm  products.  Numerically,  the  greatest 
increase  was  among  farms  between  220  and  500  acres.  These 
accounted  for  half  of  the  increase  in  Class  I  farms. 

The  number  of  farms  in  Economic  Class  II  also  increased  be- 
tween 1950  and  1954,  an  increase  of  67,696.  This  increase  took 
place  among  all  acreage-size  groups  of  farms.  Most  of  the  in- 
crease in  Class  II  farms  (over  three-fourths)  came  among  farms 
of  100  to  500  acres.  Less  than  5  percent  of  the  increase  was  among 
farms  of  500  or  more  acres. 

Farms  in  each  economic  class  below  Class  II  (sales  of  less  than 
$10,000)  decreased  in  number.  These  decreases  were  mostly 
among  the  intermediate  acreage  groups.     Among  these  classes, 


farms  below   10  acres  and  those  above  500  acres  increased  in 
number. 

The  decrease  of  nearly  400,000  farms  in  Economic  Classes  V 
and  VI  (sales  of  less  than  $2,500)  was  almost  entirely  among  farms 
between  10  and  220  acres.  For  these  classes  taken  together,  farms 
of  less  than  10  acres  and  farms  larger  than  500  acres  increased  in 
number. 


Table  10. — Number  and  Percent  Distribution  of  Farms, 
1954,  and  Change  in  Number  of  Farms,  1950  to  1954; 
by  Size  and  Economic  Class,  for  the  United  States 


Number  of  farms,  1954: 
Commercial  fauns 

Class  I 

Class  II 

Class  III.... 

Class  V. '.'.'.'.'.'.'.'.'.'.'. 
Class  VI 

Percent      distribution 
1954: 
Commercial  farms 

ClassI 

Class  II.. 

Class  III 

Class  IV 

Class  V 

Class  VI... 

Increase     or     decrease, 
1950  to  1954: 
Commercial  farms.... 

Class  li'.""'"."" 

Class  III 

Class  IV 

ClassV 

Class  VI 

1954  as  percent  of  1950: 
Commercial  farms 

ClassI   

Class  II 

Class  III 

Class  IV 

ClassV 

Class  VI 


3.  327,  889 
131.004 
448.847 
700,  S52 
SI  2.  108 
763,515 
402,  a  13 


378.523 
30,  833 
07,  000 
-  14,369 
-70,194 
137.  Mil 


-254, 


52.451 
10.  327 
47,  352 


13.  119 

25,  399 
-0,  S30 


182.5.50 
24,807 
IS,  S75 
19.087 


127,30  1 
30,774 
38,816 
30.  138 


2,  7  19 
2,840 
2,201 


102  3 
110.0 
120  2 
135.7 
112.0 


The  changes  in  acreage  as  related  to  economic  class  show  that 
among  Class  I  farms  there  has  been  an  increase  in  the  proportion 
of  smaller  acreage  units  and  a  decrease  in  the  larger  acreage  units. 
On  the  farms  with  less  than  $25,000  of  farm  products  sold,  the 
trend  has  been  toward  fewer  medium-size  acreage  units  and  an 
increasing  proportion  of  farms  below  10  acres  and  above  220  acres. 

Changes  in  the  number  of  farms  include  substantial  shifting  of 
farms  between  economic  classes  and  acreage-size  groups.  The 
total  number  of  commercial  farms  decreased  by  376,000.  Most 
land  in  those  farms  was  consolidated  with  other  farms.  The  in- 
crease in  production  from  the  larger  farmed  acreage  resulted  in 
many  farms  being  classified  in  groups  of  higher  value  of  sales. 
At  the  same  time,  increased  yields  per  acre  and  per  animal  unit 
served  to  increase  market  sales  per  farm.  This  also  caused  farms 
to  shift  into  groups  of  higher  value  of  sales.  Shifts  between 
economic  classes  also  resulted  from  reorganizations  of  farming 
systems  toward  enterprises  that  were  yielding  a  greater  return 
per  acre  of  land. 

The  increase  in  the  number  of  units  of  smaller  acreage  with 
sales  of  $25,000  or  more  is  indication  of  the  greater  possibilities 
for  developing  fairly  sizable'  business  operations  on  modest  acreages. 


26 


FARMERS  AND  FARM  PRODUCTION 


Change  in  acreage  by  type  of  farm. — Among  most  types  of 
farms  there  were  fewer  small  farms  (measured  in  acres)  and  more 
of  the  larger  ones.  The  exception  was  found  among  cash-grain 
farms  which  was  the  only  type  to  grow  in  number  during  the  period 
1950  to  1954.  While  the  number  of  farms  increased  in  each  acre- 
age-size group  for  cash-grain  farms,  there  was  a  greater  propor- 
tionate increase  in  the  smaller  farms.  This  came  from  the  shifts 
to  cash-grain  of  many  midwesteru  livestock  and  general  farms, 

Table  11. — Number  and  Percent  Distribution,  1954,  and 
Change  in  Number  of  Farms,  1950  to  1954;  by  Size  and 
Type  of  Farm,  for  the  United  States 


Item  and  type  of  farm 


Number  of  farms: 
Commercial  farms    ... 

Cash-grain 

Cotton- 

Other  field-crop 

Vegetable 

Fruit-and-nut 

Dairy 

Poultry 

Livestock  other  than 
dairy  and  poultry.. 

General 

Primarily  crop 

Primarily  live- 
stock  

Cropand  livestock 
Miscellaneous 

Percent  distribution, 
1954: 

Commercial  farms 

Cash-grain 

Cotton 

Other  field-crop 

Vegetable 

Fruit-and-nut 

Dairy 

Poultry 

Livestock  other  than 
dairy  and  poultry 

General 

Primarily  crop 

Primarily    live- 
Crop  and  iivestock 
Miscellaneous 

Increase     or     decrease, 
1950  to  1954: 

Commercial  farms 

Cash-grain. 

Cotton 

Other  field -crop 

Vegetable 

Fruit-and-nut 

Dairy 

Poultry 

Livestock  other  than 
dairy  ami  poultry  . 

General 

Primarily  crop  .. . 
Primarily    live- 
stock  

Cropandlivestuck 
M  iscellaneous 

1954  as  percent  of  1950: 

Commercial  farms 

Cash-grain 

Cotton _ 

Other  field-crop 

Vegetable 

Fruit-and-nut 

Dairy 

Poultry 

Livestock  other  than 

dairy  and  poultry- 
General 

Primarily  crop... 

Primarily  live- 
stock  

Cropand  livestock 
Miscellaneous 


...17. '.'7 1 
727.  lli.'i 

3C7, 733 
32,  581 

82,  096 

.MS.  707 
17,4.  27,1 


i,3.  I'.ir 
71,3.  s  13 

717,  (17,7 


37s.  77:: 

1117,  7S7, 

-    M.N  It 

11.  CSS 

13.S34 


337.  sin 

233.  S'Jil 
2(1.  1417. 

53,  804 

17,(1.317, 
70,  2(111 


311,  MOT 
7I.S3S 
37,  (IS3 
II!,  427, 


170,  sin 
97,  :1m 
74,  77,3 
5,752 


137.77,7 

34,  2711 

-  17,  Ills 

-2,  105 

-582 

-20,232 
-3,851 

-52, 192 

-58,  341 


II.  I  14 
22.1110 
2,412 


1S7,  7 

,,3,1,33 
13.  120 


types  that  are  typically  smaller  in  acreage  than  the  wheat  farms 
in  the  Plains  and  western  areas. 

Less  than  a  tenth  of  the  cash-grain  farms  have  500  or  more 
acres.  (See  table  11.)  The  number  of  cash-grain  farms  with 
more  than  500  acres  increased  by  15  percent.  This  increase,  how- 
ever, accounted  for  virtually  all  of  the  increase  that  took  place  in 
commercial  farms  of  500  to  1,000  acres  and  nearly  half  of  the  in- 
crease in  farms  of  1,000  acres  and  over. 

Farms  of  less  than  10  acres  decreased  for  most  types  of  farms 
but  increased  substantially  for  cotton  and  other  field-crop  farms. 
This  increase  was  probably  due  to  the  reduction  in  acreage  allot- 
ments of  cotton  and  tobacco.  Many  of  these  farms  are  operated 
by  croppers.  A  reduction  in  the  allotment  on  a  multiple-unit 
operation,  unless  accompanied  by  a  corresponding  decrease  in  the 
number  of  croppers,  usually  means  that  fewer  acres  of  land  are 
assigned  to  each  cropper.  On  other  field-crop  farms  this  was  the 
only  acreage-size  group  that  increased  in  number. 

All  of  the  net  decrease  in  the  number  of  commercial  farms  took 
place  among  farms  that  had  between  10  and  220  acres.  Decreases 
occurred  in  each  type  except  cash-grain  farms. 

Farms  of  500  acres  or  more  increased  in  number  for  most  types. 
The  exceptions  are  other  field-crop,  livestock,  and  general  farms. 
Two-thirds  of  the  increase  was  among  cash-grain  farms.  Sizable 
increases  also  occurred  for  cotton,  dairy,  and  other  livestock  farms. 

To  summarize,  changes  in  the  distribution  of  farms  by  type 
and  size  show  a  trend  toward  increasing  acreage  in  farms,  for 
most  types.  This  is  to  be  expected  during  a  period  in  which 
modern  machinery  has  enabled  a  given  labor  force  to  handle  a 
greater  acreage.  Cash-grain  farms  appear  to  be  an  exception, 
but  this  is  mainly  because  of  shifts  to  cash-grain  from  livestock 
and  general  farms  in  the  Midwest. 

CHANGES  IN  FARM  OPERATOR  CHARACTERISTICS 

Along  with  changes  in  types  and  sizes  of  farms,  there  have 
been  noticeable  changes  in  the  characteristics  of  the  farm  opera- 
tors. These  changes  are  shown  for  types  and  economic  classes 
of  farms  in  table  12.  The  changes  in  operator  characteristics  are 
interrelated  with  the  shifts  that  have  taken  place  between  types, 
economic  classes,  and  acreage-size  groups  of  farms  as  well  as  the 
overall  reduction  in  commercial  farm  numbers  and  the  sub- 
stantial migration  from  agriculture  to  nonfarm  occupations.  The 
data  are  more  adequate  for  describing  the  characteristics  in  each 
year  than  for  making  precise  estimates  of  changes  in  each  partic- 
ular type  or  economic  class. 

Age  of  operator. — By  economic  class  of  farm,  the  median  age 
of  farm  operators  increased  between  1950  and  1954  for  all  except 
Class  I  and  Class  II  farms.  On  Class  VI  farms  (which  decreased 
in  number  by  236,000),  the  median  age  increased  from  53  to  58 
years. 

These  changes  reflect  the  movement  of  young  men  out  of  agri- 
culture to  part-time  or  full-time  nonfarm  jobs  and  fewer  young 
men  taking  up  farming  on  the  smaller  farms.  The  incomes 
from  these  smaller  farms  probably  do  not  compare  favorably 
with  earnings  from  wages  and  salaries  in  nonfarm  occupations. 
The  decrease  in  median  age  for  Class  I  farms  (along  with  an 
identical  age  on  Class  II  farms)  indicates  that  some  of  the  younger 
farmers  have  taken  advantage  of  opportunities  for  increasing 
their  volume  of  farm  sales. 

By  type  of  farm,  the  median  age  of  operators  increased  for 
each  type  except  poultry  farms.  As  each  type  of  farm  has  a 
large  proportion  of  the  farms  in  the  smaller  economic  classes,  the 
effect  of  decreasing  age  among  Class  I  and  II  farmers  does  not 
become  apparent.  Decreasing  age  among  poultry  farmers  is 
related  to  the  increasing  specialization  in  broiler  and  egg  produc- 
tion. It  is  probable  that  many  younger  farmers,  having  small 
acreage,  have  reorganized  the  farms  for  specialized  poultry 
production. 


A  GENERAL  VIEW 


27 


-Specified  Farms  and  Farm-Operator  Characteristics,  by  Type  and  by  Economic  Class  for  Commercial  Farms,  for 
the  United  States:  1950  and  1954 


Median 
age  of 

operator 
(years) 

Owners, 

part- 
managers 
(percent) 

Working  off 
farm  100 
days  or 

(percent) 

Other  In- 
come greater 
than  farm 

sales 
(percent) 

Residing 
on  farm 

operated- 
percent 
total 

residence 

(percent) 

Farms  reporting 

Economic  class  and  type  of  farm 

Tractors,  ex- 
cluding 
garden 
(percent) 

Tractors 
with  no 
horses  or 

mules 
(percent) 

Commercial  farms  by  economic  class: 

47.6 
49.0 

69.1 
71.2 

9.1 
13.0 

9.1 
10.8 

95.2 
93.8 

57.9 
71.1 

27.4 

1954.. 

45.3 

Class  I 

1950.. 

46.1 
45.6 
45.2 
45.2 

81.7 
77.8 
71.3 
69.5 

8.1 
7.8 
6.3 
7.4 

4^6 
4.2 
4.4 

84.6 
84.5 
93.5 
93.0 

84.8 
91.0 

92'  4 

38.3 

1954.. 

54.5 
43.8 

1954.. 

62.8 

45.5 
46.5 
46.9 
48.5 

70.3 

70^0 
70.4 

7.0 
10.2 
11.0 
16.2 

5.3 
6.4 
10.2 
12.6 

95.5 
94.4 
95.5 
94.2 

85.0 

67]  9 
76.0 

39.5 

1954.. 

59.3 
30.8 

1954.. 

47.1 

47.9 
50.3 
53.3 

67.1 
69.9 
66.4 

17.4 

24.4 

20.7 
24.3 

95.6 
93.0 
96.5 
95.4 

41.9 
56.3 
18.5 
32.4 

20.7 

1954- 

34.4 
9.3 

18.8 

Commercial  farms  by  type: 

44.7 
47.3 
44.2 
46.2 

62.2 
67.2 
38.3 
40.7 
53.3 
56.6 

9.8 
14.6 
5.4 

a  4 

7.2 
10.4 
6.0 
6.3 
6.1 
6.5 

88.4 
89.0 
96.3 
94.5 
96.4 
94.8 

85.2 
91.8 
30.8 
41.6 
28.2 
44.0 

51.2 

Cotton 

1954.. 

16!  3 

1954- 

25.7 
9.8 

1954.. 

17.9 

Vegetable -- 

Fruit-and-nut - 

1950- 

1954.. 
1950- 

1954- 

48.6 
50.3 
54.0 
54.8 

82!  9 

93.9 
95.7 

11.5 
15.2 
21.5 
27.7 

11. 1 
13.7 
19.8 
26.1 

90.4 
87.8 
87.6 
84.5 

56.9 

59i  2 

65.7 

38.9 
55.2 
48.1 
55.1 

Poultry — 

General: 
Primarily  crop - 

Primarily  livestock 

1954.. 
1950.. 

1954- 
1950- 

1954- 

48.7 
49.0 
54.4 
53.9 
49.7 
51.0 

85.0 

9Z  7 
93.6 

78.9 
80.4 

10.2 
14.0 
18.2 
24.1 
9.5 
13.4 

9.3 
10.1 
21.6 
23.3 

9.8 
12.4 

98.0 
97.7 
97.7 
97.1 
94.8 
93.1 

71.5 
85.4 
35.8 
46.9 
67.8 
80.6 

31.5 

29!  0 

35.8 
24.1 

44.7 

1950.. 

1954.. 
1950- 

1954- 

47.1 
49.2 
50.4 
50.9 
47.6 
48.7 

71.5 
75.4 
80.2 
81.8 
73.6 
75.2 

9.6 
15.8 
7.0 
9.8 
6.7 
10.1 

10.4 
14.9 
7.7 
7.6 
7.3 
8.5 

93.2 
91.2 
98.6 
98.3 
97.7 
97.1 

57.4 

70^6 
84.6 
73.7 
88.5 

27.3 
46.4 
31.2 
56.0 
31.6 

1954.. 

54.9 

1954- 

52.1 
53.5 

92.6 
94.7 

18.1 
22.4 

20.4 
23.5 

90.6 
88.9 

29.1 
47.2 

23.2 
28.9 

Tenure  of  operator. — On  Class  I  and  Class  II  farms,  the  pro- 
portion of  tenancy  increased.  This  may  indicate  that  many  of 
the  younger  farmers  are  renting  their  land  and  equipment,  and 
using  any  cash  reserves  to  increase  the  scope  of  their  operations 
rather  than  investing  in  ownership.  Increasing  ownership  among 
the  smaller  economic  classes  of  farms  is  associated  with  the  overall 
decline  in  tenancy,  particularly  among  croppers  on  cotton  and 
tobacco  farms.  Also,  an  increasing  proportion  of  the  smallest 
economic  classes  of  farms  are  probably  serving  as  retirement 
units  for  elderly  persons  who  own  their  farms.  Three-fourths 
of  the  Class  VI  farms  were  owned,  in  full  or  in  part,  in  1954. 
This  is  the  highest  proportion  for  any  economic  class  except 
Class  I. 

There  was  an  increase  in  the  proportion  of  operators  that  were 
full  and  part  owners  for  each  type  of  farm.  In  general,  this  in- 
crease was  smallest  among  types  already  predominantly  owner 
operated.  On  the  other  hand,  cotton  and  other  field-crop  farms — 
types  that  have  a  relatively  high  proportion  of  tenant  opera- 
tors— showed  only  small  increases  in  farms  operated  by  owners 
and  part  owners. 

Off-farm  work  and  other  income. — The  proportion  of  com- 
mercial farm  operators  working  off  their  farms  100  or  more  days 
and  those  having  a  family  income  from  off-farm  sources  exceeding 
the  value  of  farm  sales,  increased  substantially  between  1950  and 


1954.  These  increases  took  place  among  each  economic  class, 
except  Class  I,  and  for  each  type  of  farm.  A  much  higher  propor- 
tion of  the  operators  on  the  smaller  economic  classes  worked  off 
the  farm  and  had  a  greater  off-farm  income  than  sales  from  the 
farm. 

The  types  of  farms  differ  considerably  in  respect  to  the  propor- 
tions of  each  type  that  reported  100  or  more  days  of  off-farm 
work  and  other  income  exceeding  sales.  For  example,  approxi- 
mately a  fourth  of  the  fruit-and-nut  and  poultry  farms  reported 
these  items  compared  with  less  than  10  percent  of  the  cotton 
and  other  field-crop  farms. 

Residence  of  farm  operator. — Virtually  all  (94  percent)  of  the 
farm  operators  live  on  the  farms  they  operate.  The  proportion 
of  nonresident  landlords  is  highest  among  Class  I  farms,  about  15 
percent.  The  smaller  economic  classes  show  small  difference  in 
respect  to  residence,  having  only  about  5  percent  nonresident 
operators.  By  type  of  farm,  the  proportion  of  nonresident 
operators  ranges  from  a  high  of  15  percent  on  fruit-and-nut 
farms  to  a  low  of  2  to  3  percent  on  dairy,  poultry,  and  general 
livestock  farms. 

Nonresident  operators  increased  between  1950  and  1954  among 
each  economic  class  except  Class  I  and  among  each  of  the  types 
of  farms. 


28 


FARMERS  AND  FARM  PRODUCTION 


CHANGES  IN  FARM  RESOURCES 

Tractors  on  farms. — Mechanization  of  farms  continued  between 
1950  and  1954.  Whereas  58  percent  of  the  commercial  farms 
reported  a  tractor  (excluding  garden  tractors)  in  1950,  the  pro- 
portion had  increased  to  71  percent  in  1954.  Approximately  90 
percent  or  more  of  Economic  Classes  I,  II,  and  III  reported 
tractors.  On  the  smaller  economic  classes,  fewer  farms  have  a 
tractor.  The  proportion  of  the  smaller  farms  reporting  a  tractor, 
however,  increased  substantially  between  1950  and  1954. 

Increasing  mechanization  (as  indicated  by  tractor  numbers) 
took  place  for  all  types  of  farms.  The  increase  was  less  for  cash- 
grain  farms  than  for  other  types  because  these  farms  were  already 
highly  mechanized.  More  than  90  percent  reported  a  tractor  in 
1954.  In  general,  the  greatest  rate  of  increase  was  among  types 
that  are  comparatively  low  in  the  proportion  of  farms  reporting 
tractors,  such  as  cotton  and  other  field-crop  farms. 

Noticeable  also,  between  1950  and  1954,  was  the  sharp  increase 
in  the  number  of  farms  that  depend  upon  tractors  alone  as  a 
source  of  work  power.  The  proportion  of  all  commercial  farms 
that  reported  a  tractor  and  no  workstock  increased  from  27 
percent  to  45  percent.  The  trend  toward  complete  dependency 
on  tractors  as  a  source  of  work  power  is  evident  on  each  economic 
class  and  each  type  of  farm.  "Horseless  farming"  is  more  common, 
however,  to  Economic  Classes  II  and  III  and  among  cash-grain, 
fruit-and-nut,  vegetable,  dairy,  and  general  farms. 

land  resources  and  market  output. — Between  1949  and  1954, 
the  value  of  farm  products  sold  by  commercial  farmers  increased  by 
12  percent  (see  table  13).  This  increase  was  accomplished  on 
approximately  the  same  land  acreage  in  farms.  The  total  land  in 
commercial  farms  increased  by  only  1  percent.  There  was  a  slight 
decrease  in  the  land  that  was  in  harvested  crops  and  an  increase 
in  the  land  that  was  pastured.  More  of  the  land  was  irrigated, 
an  increase  of  16  percent.  Irrigated  land,  however,  accounted 
for  only  3  percent  of  the  total  land  in  farms.  In  1954,  farmers 
valued  their  farmland  and  buildings  29  percent  higher  than  in  1950. 

The  larger  economic  classes  of  farms  accounted  for  an  increasing 
amount  of  land  resources  and  of  market  sales.  The  value  of  farm 
products  sold  was  a  third  greater  for  Class  I  farms  and  a  fifth 
greater  for  Class  II  farms.  On  Class  I  farms,  the  land  in  har- 
vested crops  was  a  fifth  greater.  This  increase  in  harvested  crop- 
land among  Class  I  farms  was  due  largely  to  the  greater  number  of 
cash-grain  farms  that  were  included  in  Class  I  in  1954.  The  acre- 
age of  land  pastured  on  Class  I  farms  did  not  change,  but  the 
acreage  of  land  irrigated   increased   by   nearly   two-fifths. 

The  greatest  increase  in  total  land  was  among  Class  II  farms, 
an  increase  of  12  percent.  Among  farms  in  this  class,  the  cropland 
harvested,  land  pastured,  and  land  irrigated  each  increased  by 
more  than  10  percent.  The  land  pastured  increased  on  the  smaller 
economic  classes  of  farms  whereas  there  were  decreases  in  both 
total  land  and  land  in  harvested  crops.  The  value  of  farm  products 
sold  was  approximately  the  same  for  Economic  Class  III  and 
decreased  on  Classes  IV,  V,  and  VI. 

By  type  of  farm,  there  was  an  increasing  concentration  of  land 
resources  and  market  sales  on  cash-grain  farms.  The  value  of 
farm  products  sold  on  cash-grain  farms  increased  by  more  than 
two-fifths.  The  land  in  farms  and  the  harvested  cropland  increased 
substantially,  but  the  greatest  change  was  in  land  pastured — an 
increase  of  a  fourth  in  acreage.  This  increase  was  influenced  by 
the  shift  into  the  cash-grain  category  of  many  farms  classified 
in  1950  as  livestock  and  general.  A  higher  proportion  of  the 
cash-grain  farms  in  1954  were  in  the  Midwest.  These  farms  have 
a  larger  proportion  of  the  land  in  pasture  than  the  cash-grain 
farms  in  the  Plains  area  farther  west.  There  was  a  decrease  of 
nearly  half  in  the  land  resources  contained  in  general  livestock 
farms  between  1950  and  1954. 

By  far  the  greatest  increase  in  land  irrigated  was  on  cotton 
farms — an  increase  of  60  percent.  This  came  about  mostly  in 
the  western  cotton-producing  areas. 


Table  13. — Specified  Farm  Resources,  Percent  1954  is  of  1950, 
by  Economic  Class  and  by  Type  of  Farm,  for  the  United 

States 


Economic  class  and  type 
of  farm 

Num- 
ber of 

(per- 
cent) 

Land  in 
cent) 

Crop- 
land 
har- 
vested 
(per- 
cent) 

All 
pas- 
(per- 

'(Per- 
cent) 

Value 

■  it  hnnl 

and 
build- 
ings 
(per- 
cent) 

Value 
of  all 

prod- 
sold 
(per- 
cent) 

Economic  class  of  farm: 

All  commercial  farms 

90 
130 
118 
98 
92 
85 
64 

90 
125 
86 
90 
70 

100 
91 
88 

86 

95 

47 

74 
74 

101 
104 
112 
103 
97 
93 
74 

1C1 
119 

88 
88 

124 
100 
94 

101 

103 

52 

84 
102 

98 
119 
113 

96 

89 
81 
58 

98 
116 

94 
85 
90 

112 
51 

84 

105 
100 
112 
110 
106 
106 

105 
124 
116 
99 
98 

117 
101 

104 

99 

55 

88 
120 

116 
139 
115 
94 

86 

75 

116 
122 
159 
106 
102 

97 
113 
82 

100 

96 
120 

129 
167 
145 
119 
111 
108 
84 

129 
153 
135 
120 
126 

149 
122 
116 

125 

145 

105 
127 

112 

Type  of  farm : 

Cotton 

Other  field-crop 

Vegetable 

Fruit-and-nut 

118 
108 
104 

160 

Poultry 

Livestock  other  than 
dairy  and  poultry 

General: 

Primarily  crop 

Primarily        live- 

124 
98 

134 

Crop     and      live- 
stock  

Miscellaneous 

96 
103 

Notwithstanding  decreases  in  the  number  of  farms  for  most 
types  of  farms,  there  was  an  increase  in  irrigated  land  among  all 
types  except  fruit-and-nut,  poultry,  general  livestock,  and  general 
crop  and  livestock  farms. 

The  value  of  land  and  buildings  for  commercial  farms  increased 
by  29  percent  between  1950  and  1954.  Part  of  this  increase  is  due 
to  improvements,  such  as  improved  pastures  and  new  and  better 
houses  and  farm  buildings,  made  to  the  land.  The  increases 
also  reflect  increases  in  land  values. 

Between  1950  and  1954,  land  values  rose  much  more  than  market 
sales  for  each  economic  class  and  type  of  farm.  The  increase  of 
two-thirds  in  the  value  of  land  and  buildings  on  Class  I  farms  is 
associated  with  an  increase  of  only  a  third  in  gross  farm  sales  and 
an  increase  of  but  a  fifth  in  the  number  of  farms.  On  Class  II 
farms,  land  value  increased  more  than  two-fifths;  sales  of  farm 
products  increased  by  one-fifth.  On  the  smaller  economic  classes 
as  well,  there  was  an  increase  in  value  relative  to  the  volume  of 
farm  sales. 

Increasing  land  values  relative  to  market  sales  took  place  on 
each  type  of  farm  with  the  exception  of  fruit-and-nut  farms  and 
poultry  farms.  Prices  received  by  farmers  for  fruits  were  12 
percent  higher  in  1954  than  in  1949;  poultry  and  egg  prices, 
however,  were  20  percent  lower.  The  increase  in  market  sales 
relative  to  land  value  probably  relates  to  shifts  in  the  geographic 
concentration  of  poultry  production  and  to  developments  that 
have  encouraged  more  intensive  production  of  broilers  and  eggs  on 
fairly  small  acreages. 

The  increase  in  land  values  between  1950  and  1954  can  be 
explained  partly  by  the  strong  demand  for  land  by  farmers  who 
wanted  to  enlarge  their  farms,  for  the  increasing  mechanization  of 
farms  means  that  more  land  can  be  handled  with  the  same  or  a 
smaller  labor  force.  Farmers  that  bought  tractors  and  related 
equipment  have  frequently  been  faced  with  the  need  to  enlarge 
their  farms  in  order  to  utilize  their  machinery  more  efficiently, 
and  provide  full  employment  for  their  labor  force.  It  is  also 
probable  that  increasing  land  values  have  resulted  from  the  growth 
of  towns  and  cities  and  the  increasing  demand  for  land  for  resi- 
dential and  other  purposes. 


A  GENERAL  VIEW 


29 


CHARACTERISTICS  OF  TYPE  OF  FARM  BY  ECONOMIC  CLASS 


The  structure  of  farming  today  reflects  the  changes  that  have 
affected  farmers  so  differently.  Close  attention  to  this  structure 
is  basic  to  an  understanding  of  the  problems  confronting  farmers 
and  of  the  adjustments  that  are  needed  in  a  changing  Nation. 

Farm  Operator  Characteristics 

Color  and  tenure  of  operator. — In  1954,  71  percent  of  the 
operators  of  commercial  farms  were  owners,  part  owners,  or  man- 
agers.    (See  table  14.)     This  was  an  increase  from  69  percent  in 


Table  14. — Proportion  of  Farms  Operated  by  Owners, 
Part-Owners,  and  Managers,  and  Croppers,  and  by 
White  and  Nonwhite  Operators,  for  Each  Type  of  Farm 
by  Economic  Class,  for  the  United  States:  1954 


Total 

Economic  class  of  farm 

1 

II 

III 

IV 

V 

VI 

FULL  OWNERS,  PART  OWNERS. 
AND  MANAGERS 

All  commercial  farms,  total 

71.2 
67.2 
40.7 
56.  7 
82  9 

95.7 
86.  4 
93.6 

80.4 

75.4 
81.8 
75.2 
94.7 

76.0 
67.3 
54.4 
64.0 
85.1 

96.4 

93!  6 

SO.  4 

78.2 
81.8 
75.2 
95.3 

28.7 
22.7 
30.9 
68.5 

7.3 
28.7 
21.3 

0.5 

3.2 
14.4 
14.7 

0.4 

43.5 
47.5 
44.5 
10.2 

77  v 
70  3 
69.8 

Ml    X 

78  5 

95  7 

82.  2 
91.4 

71.7 

80.3 
82.1 

77.(1 
95.3 

77.8 
70.2 

8L7 

79.3 

96.5 
82.1 

"1    1 

71.7 

80.2 

82.  1 
76.8 
95.6 

75.9 
68  v 
64  7 

0.4 
1.4 

0.7 
0.2 

0.4 
1.4 
0.6 
0.2 

0.9 
8.9 
1.7 
0.1 

69.5 

:,s   :, 
58.fi 
68.0 
82.  2 

94.  r, 
79  7 
93.3 

66.  4 

71    5 
09.3 
64.0 

58^5 
58.9 
70.0 
83.4 

95.7 
79.7 
93.  4 

06.4 

71.9 
69.2 
64.0 
93.4 

60.7 
49.5 

;o  .; 
74.1 

0.6 
3.5 

1,  11 
0.3 

0.5 

3.1 
4.4 

n  1' 

11.3 
17.0 
34.2 
2.0 

70.6 
62.0 
II    7 
47.  6 
81.2 

•17.  .'. 

83  3 
94.  3 

74.7 

69.5 
72.7 
67. 1 
93.9 

72.0 
62.0 
50.4 
55.2 
84.6 

96.1 
83.3 
94.3 

74.7 

71.6 
72.7 
67.1 
95.0 

24.3 
18.7 
16.4 
60.6 

2.9 
16.5 
22.7 

0.4 

1.6 
9.5 
14.9 
0.3 

15.  5 

49.0 
54.7 
10.8 

70!  0 

35.9 

45  6 

96,  4 

88.5 
93.  9 

S4  4 

72.2 

84.4 

94!  7 

76.0 
70.1 
49.0 
54.9 

96.5 
88.6 

91   II 

84.5 

77.2 
84.4 
77.fi 
95.3 

20.3 
15.6 
20.5 
57.0 

32!  5 
28.1 
0.6 

4.2 

17.4 

18.8 

0.4 

52.2 
55.7 
53  11 
19  0 

69.9 
77.  9 
:i4.0 
.58.6 
84.9 

96.5 
90.9 
94.1 

89.2 

78.9 
89.8 
85.7 
95.3 

79  4 

78.1 
51.7 
65.7 
87.2 

96.9 
90.9 
94.2 

89.3 

82.7 
89.8 

.85  9 

95.8 

23.9 
16.8 
35.5 
67.1 

13.1 
37.6 
22.0 
0.8 

5.5 
19.3 
16.3 

0.6 

49.  5 
55.4 
40.4 
12.1 

75.2 

Fruit-and-nut 

96.1 

Livestock    other    than    dairy    and 

General: 

Primarily  crop 

84.8 

Livestock  oilier  than  dairy  and 

General: 

CROPPERS 
All  commercial  farms,  total 

9.6 

1950.  All  tenants  (including  croppers)  operated  29  percent  of 
the  commercial  farms. 

Ownership  of  the  land  is  more  common  among  operators  of 
some  types  of  farms  than  others.  More  than  90  percent  of  the 
operators  of  fruit-and-nut  and  poultry  farms  were  included  in  the 
ownership  group.  The  lowest  proportions  of  owners  are  among 
cotton  farmers  (41  percent),  other  field-crop  farmers  (57  percent), 
and  cash-grain  farmers  (67  percent).  On  all  other  types  of  farms 
the  ownership  ranged  between  75  percent  and  90  percent. 

For  all  commercial  farms  as  a  group,  the  highest  proportion  of 
ownership  is  found  among  Class  I  farms  (78  percent)  followed 
closely  by  Class  VI  farms  (75  percent).  This  varies  considerably 
by  type  of  farm,  however.  On  vegetable  farms,  dairy  farms, 
poultry  farms,  and  other  livestock  farms,  ownership  is  lowest 
among  Classes  I  and  II. 

A  much  higher  proportion  of  the  white  operators,  than  of 
nonwhite  operators,  were  owners,  part  owners,  and  managers,  in 
1954:  76  percent  for  white  operators  compared  with  29  percent 
for  nonwhite  operators.  Among  both  white  and  nonwhite  oper- 
ators, ownership  was  lowest  among  operators  of  cotton  and  other 
field-crop  farms.  Among  these  types  of  farms,  ownership  was 
lowest  for  the  intermediate  classes  and  highest  on  Class  I  and 
Class  VI. 

The  high  proportion  of  tenancy  among  cotton  and  other  field- 
crop  farms  and  among  nonwhite  operators  is  influenced  by  the 
counting  of  cropper  units  as  farms.  Most  of  the  croppers  (95 
percent)  are  found  among  cotton  and  other  field-crop  farms.  (See 
table  1 5.)  Also  more  than  90  percent  of  the  nonwhite  operators 
are  found  among  these  two  types  of  farms. 

Nearly  half  of  the  nonwhite  operators  on  cotton  and  other  field- 
crop  farms  were  croppers  in  1954.  They  were  concentrated  in 
the  smaller  economic  classes  of  farms. 


Table  15. — Percent  Distribution  of  Farms  in  Each  Tenure 
and  Color  Group  by  Type  and  Economic  Class  of  Farm, 
for  the  United  States:  1954 


Type  and  economic  class  of  farm 

Owners, 

part-own- 
ers, and 

maiiaL'rls 

All  ten- 
ants 

Croppers 

White 
operators 

Nonwhite 

operators 

Type  of  farm : 

100.0 
15.3 
9.0 
8.8 
1,  1 

3.3 

20.0 
6.1 

23.6 

2.5 
2.2 

lie 

100.0 
4.4 

13.2 
21.1 
24.1 
22,5 
14.7 

100.0 
18.4 
32.5 
16.6 

0.4 
7.7 
1.0 

14.2 

2.0 
1.2 
5.3 
0.2 

100.0 
3.1 

14.3 
21.6 
25.1 
24.0 
12.0 

100.0 
1.2 
62.3 
32.3 
0.2 

m 

0.3 
0.8 

.  '  6 
0!  1 

100.0 
0.2 
1.2 
8.6 
30.3 
41.3 
18.4 

100.0 
17.9 
10.0 

L0 

2.7 
18.3 

23.0 

2.  1 
6.7 

100.0 

R9 
22.9 
24.4 
21.2 
12.2 

Fruit-and-nut 

0.8 

Livestock  other  than  dairy 

General: 

2.2 

Primarily  livestock 

Crop  and  livestock 

0.1 
0.7 

Economic  class  of  farm : 

1.2 

24.4 

28.8 

i  than  0.05  percent. 


30 


FARMERS  AND  FARM  PRODUCTION 


Residence  of  farm  operators. — Most  farm  families  live  on  the 
farm  they  operate.  In  1954,  only  6  percent  of  all  commercial 
farm  operators  reported  that  they  did  not  live  on  the  farm  (see 
table  16).  The  highest  proportions  of  nonresident  operators  were 
on  fruit-and-nut  farms  (15  percent),  vegetable  farms  (12  percent), 
and  cash-grain  farms  (11  percent;.  The  lowest  proportions  of 
nonresident  operators  were  on  dairy,  poultry,  and  general  farms. 


Table  16. — Percent  of  Nonresident  Operators  for  Type  of 
Farm  by  Economic  Class,  for  the  United  States:  1954 


Total 

Economic  class  of  farm 

I 

II 

III 

IV 

V 

VI 

6.2 
11.0 

5.S 
6.2 
12.2 

15.5 
2.3 
2.9 

6.9 

8.8 
1.7 
2.9 

15.5 
16.2 
23.0 
18.0 
33.8 

21.1 

7.7 
8.2 

12.2 

22.2 
6.7 
9.4 

24.0 

7.0 
9.0 

13.2 
7.2 

14.6 

16.9 
3.5 
3.3 

6.2 

9.2 
2.2 
3.4 
15.3 

5.6 
9.0 

3^9 
10.1 

17.2 
2.2 
2.6 

5.8 

7.8 
1.8 
2.5 
11.6 

5.8 
12.1 
4.7 
4.1 
9.2 

15.4 
1.9 
2.5 

7.0 

7.4 
0.4 
2.9 
9.8 

6.1 
14.2 
4.0 
5.7 
9.1 

13.2 
2.0 
2.2 

8.5 

8.7 
1.6 
2.6 
7.0 

Cash-grain. 

11.6 

5.4 

1.7 

Livcslork  otln  r  than  dairy  and  poul- 

Oeneral: 

Among  operators  of  each  type  of  farm  the  proportion  of  non- 
residence  was  higher  for  Class  I  farms  than  for  the  smaller  economic 
classes.  Except  for  Class  I,  however,  there  is  no  strong  relation- 
ship between  residence  of  the  operator  and  the  value  of  farm  sales. 

A  substantially  higher  proportion  of  the  farmers  on  Class  I 
farms  lived  away  from  their  farms,  where  the  major  source  of 
farm  sales  was  from  crops.  A  third  of  the  operators  of  Class  I 
vegetable  farms  and  approximately  a  fifth  of  those  on  Class  I 
cotton  farms,  other  field-crop  farms,  fruit-and-nut  farms,  and 
general  farms  did  not  live  on  their  farms  in  1954.  On  Class  I 
dairy  and  poultry  farms,  for  example,  only  about  8  percent  of 
the  operators  were  nonresidents. 

Work  off  the  farm  and  other  income. — The  proportion  of  farm 
operators  working  off  their  farms  100  or  more  days,  or  reporting 
that  family  income  from  nonfarm  sources  exceeded  the  value  of 
farm  sales,  was  greater  among  the  smaller  economic  classes  of 
farms  (see  tables  17  and  18).  These  proportions  were  lowest 
among  cotton  and  other  field-crop  farms  and  highest  among 
fruit-and-nut  and  poultry  farms.  Fruit-and-nut  farms  also 
reported  the  highest  proportion  of  nonresident  operators  and 
poultry  farms  were  among  the  lowest. 

Approximately  half  of  the  operators  of  Class  V  fruit-and-nut 
farms  and  two-fifths  of  those  on  poultry  farms  worked  off  their 
farms  100  or  more  days  or  had  other  income  that  exceeded  farm 
sales.  In  contrast,  only  a  tenth  of  the  cotton  and  other  field-crop 
farms  so  reported. 

Age  of  operator. — The  median  age  of  operator  increased  with 
decreasing  size  (as  measured  by  gross  sales  of  farm  products) 
for  each  type  of  farm  (see  table  19).  On  several  types  (cash-grain, 
dairy,  other  livestock,  and  general  farms)  the  operators  of  Class  I 
farms  were  older  than  those  of  Class  II  farms.  The  median  age 
of  Class  VI  farm  operators  was  over  65  years  on  poultry  farms  and 
nearly  65  years  on  fruit-and-nut  and  general  livestock  farms. 


Table  17- — Operators  Working  Off  the  Farm  100  or  More 
Days  as  Percentage  of  Operators  Reporting  as  to  Off- 
farm  Work,  for  Each  Type  of  Farm,  by  Economic  Class, 
for  the  United  States:  1954 


Total 

Economic  class  of  farm 

I 

II 

III 

IV 

V 

VI 

13.3 
15.0 

7.9 
8.5 
15.4 

27.9 
14.4 

24.7 

13.7 

lfi.O 
10.1 
10.3 
23.0 

8.0 

4.9 
7.3 

S   II 

8.1 

13.3 

8.3 
14.5 

6.1 

8.2 
10.0 

5.1 
10.2 

7.6 
5.6 
9.3 
7.2 
9.7 

19.2 

20.2 

5.3 

7.9 
5.0 
4.5 
17.0 

10.4 

9.9 
9.8 
6.1 
14.6 

28.9 
10.0 
29.8 

8.6 

11.6 
6.6 
6.6 

22.7 

16.5 
21.1 
9.5 
7.7 
23.2 

37.4 
18.2 

36.6 

18.4 

17.8 
11.3 
12.2 
32.8 

24.6 
36.4 
12.0 
15.2 
31.5 

47.1 
28.3 
40.1 

33.9 

30.4 
19.8 
20.8 
41.4 

Livestock  iittier  than  dairy  and  poul- 

General: 

Table  18. — Percentage  of  Farms  With  Other  Income 
Greater  Than  the  Value  of  Farm  Products  Sold,  for 
Each  Type  of  Farm,  by  Economic  Class,  for  the  United 
States:  1954 


Total 

Economic  class  of  farm 

I 

II 

m 

IV 

V 

VI 

10.8 
10.4 
6.3 
6.5 
13.7 

26.1 
10.1 
23.3 

12.4 

14.9 
7.7 
8.6 

23.6 

4.6 
1.9 

2.8 
3.1 
4.5 

7.1 
6.4 

4.2 

3.9 
7.8 
4.1 
7.5 

4.4 
2.2 
4.4 
2.9 
6.4 

13.2 
3.6 
16.0 

3.4 

5.2 
1.9 
2.0 
14.7 

6.4 
4.6 
6.8 
3.4 
10.7 

24.1 
4.8 
25.7 

6.3 

7.9 
2.8 
3.5 
20.9 

12.6 
14.0 
6.5 
6.3 
18.9 

36.6 

11.6 
34.7 

16.0 

15.6 
8.0 
9.8 

32.7 

24.3 
33.3 
11.3 
13.4 
34.7 

53.8 
26.2 
45.5 

34.6 

32.9 

19.6 
21.6 
48.5 

Livestock  other  than  dairy  and  poul- 

General: 

Table  19. — Median  Age  of  Operator  for  Type  of  Farm  by 
Economic  Class,  for  the  United  States:  1954 


Total 

Economic  class  of  farm 

I 

II 

III 

IV 

V 

VI 

49.0 
47.3 
47.3 
46.2 
50.  3 

64.8 

49.0 
53.9 

51.0 

49.2 
50.9 
48.7 
53.5 

45.6 
44.0 
43.2 
44.8 
44.8 

50.6 
47.1 
45.7 

45.6 

46.3 
45.3 
45.7 
50.0 

45.2 
43.9 
44.9 
44.1 
47.0 

52.5 
45.8 
47.7 

45.1 

45.0 
43.1 
43.6 
50.4 

46.5 
45.6 
45.8 
44.3 
47.9 

54.3 
45.9 
50.4 

48.0 

46.4 
45.2 
45.2 
51.0 

48.5 
49.0 
46.1 
43.8 
50.1 

65.7 
48.6 
53.3 

51.5 

47.7 
50.7 

Hi.  :■ 
52.4 

60.3 
50.6 
46.4 
46.4 
61.6 

65.5 
52.0 
57.0 

53.9 

50.7 
56.2 
53.0 
54.6 

Cotton 

51.0 

65+ 

Livestock    other    than    dairy    and 

61.?. 

General: 

64.8 

«!.» 

A  GENERAL  VIEW 


31 


Man-Equivalents  of  Labor  Used 

For  the  purpose  of  showing  the  amount  of  farm  labor  used  on 
commercial  farms,  all  labor  was  converted  to  a  man-equivalent 
basis.  This  was  necessary  in  order  that  meaningful  comparisons 
might  be  made  between  the  different  types  and  sizes  of  farms. 

Getting  an  estimate  of  the  labor  used  is  more  difficult  in  agri- 
culture than  for  most  other  industries.  Farming,  generally,  is 
highly  seasonal.  Certain  farming  operations  performed  during 
the  year,  such  as  cultivating  and  harvesting,  usually  require  more 
labor  than  is  needed  for  the  remainder  of  the  year. 

The  seasonal  needs  for  labor  in  farming  vary  between  different 
types  of  farms  and  between  farms  in  different  geographic  locations. 
Therefore,  data  on  the  number  of  workers,  if  based  on  any  given 
week,  are  likely  to  be  less  representative  of  the  annual  average 
on  some  farms  than  on  others.  Many  wives  and  children  of  farm- 
ers work  part  time  at  field  work  and  chores.  The  farmer  himself 
frequently  does  not  work  full  time  on  the  farm  hut  may  have  a 
nonfarm  job  or  business. 

For  these  reasons,  the  total  farm  labor  used  was  estimated  in 
man-equivalents  from  use  of  other  data  obtained  by  the  Census. 
As  used  in  this  report,  a  man-equivalent  of  labor  is  a  relative 
measure  of  employment.  The  estimates  are  designed  primarily 
toward  the  objective  of  securing  rough  comparability  in  the 
amount  of  labor  used  between  types  and  sizes  of  farms.  A  man- 
equivalent,  as  used  here,  represents  approximately  a  man-year 
of  farm  work,  but  no  attempt  is  made  to  specify  the  exact  number 
of  days  or  hours  represented. 

Operator  labor. — The  farm  operator  was  considered  to  be  equal 
to  1  man-equivalent  of  farm  labor  unless  he  worked  off  the  farm 
or  was  65  years  of  age  or  older.  Farm  operators  who  worked 
off  the  farm  1  to  99  days  were  estimated  at  0.85,  those  working 
off  the  farm  100  to  199  days  at  0.5  and  those  working  off  the  farm 
200  or  more  days  at  0.15  man-equivalents  of  labor.  A  reduction 
of  0.5  man-equivalents  was  made  for  each  operator  who  was  65 
years  or  older. 

As  estimated  in  this  report,  farm-operator  labor  per  farm  is  a 
fairly  constant  factor  in  the  labor  force.  For  most  types  of 
farms  his  labor  amounted  to  between  0.7  and  0.8  man-equivalents 
(see  table  20).  Operator  labor  on  cotton  and  other  field-crop 
farms  was  slightly  higher  and  on  fruit-and-nut  farms  and  poultry 
farms  was  slightly  lower  than  this  range. 

By  economic  class  of  farm,  operator  labor  tended  to  be  higher 
on  Class  I  farms  for  most  types  and  decreased  with  decreasing 
size  of  farm.  For  each  type  of  farm,  however,  operator  labor  per 
farm  was  higher  on  Class  VI  than  on  Class  V  farms.  This  is 
because  Class  VI  farms,  by  definition,  had  no  operators  who 
worked  off  the  farm  as  much  as  100  days.  The  relatively  small 
amount  of  operator  labor  on  Class  VI  farms  is  due  to  the  higher 
proportion  of  operators  who  were  65  years  or  older. 

Unpaid  family  labor. — The  number  of  family  members  who  were 
reported  working  15  or  more  hours  without  pay  during  the  specified 
calendar  week  (September  26-Oetober  2  or  October  24r-30,  de- 
pending on  the  date  of  enumeration)  were  estimated  at  0.5  man- 
equivalents  each.  This  reduction  was  made  in  recognition  of  the 
higher  composition  of  children  and  elderly  persons  in  the  unpaid 
family  labor  force.  Individually,  these  are  not  usually  considered 
t  he  equivalent  of  an  able-bodied  adult  worker. 


Unpaid  family  labor,  as  estimated,  amounted  only  from  one-fourth 
to  one-half  as  much  as  the  operator  labor.  The  larger  economic 
classes  of  farms  naturally  had  the  most  operator  labor.  Unpaid 
family  labor  was  most  important  on  the  intermediate  sizes  (Classes 
II,  III,  and  IV);  it  ranged  from  one-third  to  one-half  man-equiv- 
alents on  most  types.  Highest  in  use  of  unpaid  family  labor 
were  cotton,  other  field-crop,  dairy,  and  general  livestock  farms. 
The  lowest  were  fruit-and-nut,  cash-grain,  and  other  livestock 
farms. 


Table  20. — Average  Man-Equivalents  of  Labor  Used  on 
Each  Type  of  Farm  by  Economic  Class,  for  the  United 
States:  1954 


Type  of  farm 

Total 

Economic  class  of  farm 

I 

II 

III 

IV 

V 

VI 

All  commercial  farms 

1.46 
0.78 
0.34 
0.34 

1.23 
0.77 
0.25 
0.20 

1.70 
0.86 
0.48 
0.36 

1.51 
0.85 
0.40 
0.27 

3.  57 
0.76 
0.31 
2.49 

2.46 
0.64 
0.19 
1.62 

1.44 
0.77 
0.40 
0.26 

1.16 
0.65 
0.29 
0.21 

1.30 
0.76 
0.26 
0.28 

1.61 
0.76 
0.30 
0.56 

1.29 
0.79 
0.40 
0.11 

1.37 
0.81 
0.38 
0.18 

2.73 
0.68 
0.22 
1.83 

5.42 

0^27 
4.29 

:-;  (17 
0.89 
0.27 

7.76 
0.90 
0.16 
6.70 

8.59 

0^29 
7.44 

17  82 

II    S.S 

0.23 

16.71 

9.01 
0.80 
0.18 
8.04 

5.36 
0.85 
0.33 
4.17 

2.71 
0.83 
0.36 
1.52 

3.27 

II..H7 
II  2S 

2.12 

7.93 

II  si; 
0.24 

:;  79 

11  M' 

0.49 

2   IS 

4.33 
n  s7 
0.40 
3.06 

12.29 
0.82 
0.20 

11.26 

0.35 
0.60 

1.51 
0.87 
0.31 
0.33 

2.51 
0.87 
0.25 
1.39 

2.42 

ll  S7 
0.41 
1.14 

3.59 
0.84 
0.40 
2.35 

2.63 
0.74 
0.22 
1.67 

1.97 

n  si; 
0.44 
0.67 

1.43 

0.77 
0.38 
0.27 

1.61 
0.87 
a  32 
0.42 

2.07 
0.85 
0.31 
0.90 

1.69 
0.88 
0.49 
0.31 

1.74 
0.88 
0.44 
0.42 

2.80 
0.77 
0.27 
1.76 

1.43 
0.83 
0.38 
0.22 

1.23 
0.82 
0.29 
0.12 

1.93 
0.87 
0.57 
0.49 

1.79 
0.89 
0.57 
0.33 

2.00 

a  78 

0.37 

1.61 
0.65 
0.22 

1.46 
0.83 
0.45 
0.19 

1.13 

0^36 
0.10 

1.33 
0.83 
0.31 
0.19 

1.53 
0.82 
0.35 
0.35 

1.42 
0.86 
0.46 
0.10 

1.42 

o  si; 

0.42 
0.14 

1.66 
0.72 
0.28 
0.66 

1.27 
0.77 
0.39 
0.11 

1.00 
0.70 
0.24 
0.07 

1.68 
0.87 
0.66 
0.15 

1.50 

0.88 

n   III 
0.13 

1.43 
0.72 
0.36 
0.36 

1.12 
0.56 
0.19 
0.36 

1.25 
0.76 
0.43 
0.07 

0.94 
0.59 
0.30 
0.05 

1.12 
0.73 
0.27 
0.12 

1.25 

0^33 
0.15 

1.26 

0.79 
0.42 
0.05 

1.26 

0^39 
0.07 

I.  16 
0.62 
0.24 
0.30 

1.09 

II  711 
0.34 
0.05 

0.83 
0.60 
0.19 
0.04 

1.40 
0.84 
0.51 
0.05 

1.21 

0^35 
0.06 

1.08 
0.63 
0.30 
0.15 

0.86 
0.49 

(l.  is 
0.18 

1.05 
0.65 
0.37 
0.03 

0.77 
0.51 
0.24 
0.02 

0.88 

II.  no 
0.21 
0.07 

1.00 
0.65 
0.28 
0.07 

1.05 
0.68 
0.34 
0.03 

1.07 
0.70 
0.32 
0.04 

0.86 
0.54 
0.20 
0.12 

1.04 

1  07 

Unpaid  family  labor 

0.16 

Poultry 

0.81 

Unpaid  family  labor 

0.14 

Livestock  other  than  dairy  and  poultry. 

0.94 

General,  primarily  livestock 

0.91 

Unpaid  family  labor 

0.21 

General,  crop  and  livestock 

1.04 

Unpaid  family  labor 

0.  16 

32 


FARMERS  AND  FARM  PRODUCTION 


Hired  labor. — Man-equivalents  of  hired  labor  were  computed 
by  dividing  the  expenditure  for  hired  labor  by  the  annual  cash 
wage  reported  for  regular  hired  workers  for  each  type  of  farm. 

Hired  labor  is  relatively  unimportant  in  commercial  farming 
as  a  whole.  The  man-equivalents  of  hired  labor  per  farm  totaled 
about  0.3  man-equivalent  per  farm  in  1954.  Only  on  vegetable, 
fruit-and-nut,  and  general  crop  farms,  did  hired  labor  exceed 
this  amount.  However,  hired  labor  is  of  considerable  importance 
on  the  larger  economic  classes  of  farms.  The  average  for  Class 
I  farms  of  all  types  was  more  than  4  man-equivalents  per  farm  in 
1954.  The  average  vegetable  farm  in  Class  I  hired  the  equivalent 
of  17  full-time  workers  that  year.  Eight  man-equivalents  of 
hired  labor  were  used  on  Class  I  fruit-and-nut  farms  and  7  man- 
equivalents  on  Class  I  cotton  and  other  field-crop,  and  general 
crop  farms.  In  contrast,  Class  I  cash-grain  and  poultry  farms 
used  less  than  2  man-equivalents  of  hired  labor  per  farm. 

Hired  labor  comprises  a  very  small  part  of  the  farm  labor  force 
on  farms  in  the  smaller  economic  classes.  For  economic  classes 
smaller  than  Class  I  it  was  less  important  than  family  labor  on 
all  types,  with  the  exception  of  Class  II  cotton,  vegetable,  and 
fruit-and-nut  farms.  The  use  of  hired  labor  decreases  with 
decreasing  size  of  farm  for  all  types. 

Cash  Wages  Paid 

The  land  and  labor  resources  and  the  value  of  investment  for 
types  of  farms  classified  by  economic  class  is  useful  as  a  measure 
of  overall  distribution  of  resources  of  production.  When  these 
resources  are  taken  together  there  is  a  close  association  between 
the  amount  and  value  of  resources  and  the  value  of  farm  products 
sold. 

Both  the  value  of  investment  and  the  value  of  farm  products 
are  frequently  used  as  measures  of  farm  size.  In  the  purely 
physical  sense  they  appear  to  represent  fairly  adequate  measures. 
But  interest  in  farm  size  also  stems  from  concern  over  the  human 
factor  in  farming.  As  farms  increase  in  size,  measured  by  business 
volume,  there  is  a  tendency  for  the  farming  to  involve  more  work 
than  can  be  handled  by  the  farm  family,  and  for  hired  labor  to 
become  an  increasingly  important  element  in  the  day-to-day 
operations.  Many  persons  have  taken  the  increases  in  size  of 
farm  to  mean  a  trend  toward  large-scale  farms  and  a  corresponding 
increase  in  the  use  of  hired  labor  in  agriculture. 

Since  the  economic  classification  has,  as  its  largest  size  group- 
ing, farms  that  had  sales  of  farm  products  valued  at  $25,000  or 
more,  there  is  a  tendency  for  these  to  be  treated  as  representing 
large-scale  operations  employing  much  hired  labor.  Actually, 
many  of  these  farms  do  employ  a  great  deal  of  hired  work.  On 
many  others  the  work  is  done  primarily  by  members  of  the  family. 
Furthermore,  there  is  considerable  variation  by  type  of  farm 
among  Class  I  farms  in  the  amount  of  hired  labor  employed. 

Table  21  and  table  22  show  the  number  and  proportion  of 
farms  reporting  specified  amounts  paid  for  hired  labor  for  types 
of  farms  by  economic  class.  Even  among  Class  I  farms,  only 
two-fifths  reported  an  expenditure  of  $5,000  or  more.  An  expend- 
iture of  $5,000  would  probably  represent  the  hiring  of  2  to  3 
full-time  workers  at  current  wage  rates  for  hired  labor. 


By  type  of  farm,  Class  I  farms  show  striking  differences  in  the 
proportion  that  paid  $5,000  or  more  for  hired  labor.  Only  a  fifth 
of  the  Class  I  cash-grain  farms  hired  this  amount  of  farm  labor, 
reflecting  the  outstanding  progress  that  has  been  made  in  mech- 
anization of  the  entire  farming  operation  of  the  cash-grains.  In 
contrast,  other  types  of  farming  having  a  major  source  of  income 
from  crops  use  much  more  hired  labor  in  producing  $25,000  or 
more  of  farm  products  for  sale.  On  cotton,  other  field-crop,  and 
fruit-and-nut  farms,  two-thirds  to  three-fourths,  and  on  vegetable 
farms  nearly  90  percent,  of  the  Class  I  farms  had  $5,000  or  more 
expended  for  hired  work.  On  these  types  of  farms  much  labor  is 
needed  because  many  of  the  peak  harvest  operations  are  not  com- 
pletely mechanized.     Much  of  the  labor  hired  on  these  farms  is 


Livestock  and  poultry  production  is  associated  with  relatively 
small  use  of  hired  labor,  relative  to  sales.  Even  on  Class  I  farms 
only  a  fifth  of  the  poultry  and  a  fourth  of  the  livestock  farms  had 
a  labor  expenditure  of  $5,000  or  more.  About  half  of  the  dairy 
farmers  in  Class  I  reported  an  expenditure  of  $5,000  or  more. 
Dairy  and  poultry  farms  characteristically  buy  large  quantities 
of  feed.  Many  livestock  farmers,  particularly  those  engaged  in 
cattle  and  hog  fattening,  have  high  expenditures  for  purchases 
of  feeder  cattle  and  pigs.  On  these  types  of  farms  a  smaller 
proportion  of  the  gross  sales  is  net  than  for  most  specialized  crop 
farms. 

Farms  with  expenditures  for  hired  labor  of  $5,000  or  more  are 
not  restricted  to  Class  I  farms,  however.  More  than  a  fourth  of 
the  farms  employing  this  much  hired  work  were  classified  as 
Class  II.  A  fairly  high  proportion  of  Class  II  cotton,  other  field- 
crop,  vegetable,  and  fruit-and-nut  farms,  reported  hiring  this 
much  farm  labor. 

On  the  smaller  economic  classes  of  farms  (those  with  sales  of 
farm  products  valued  at  less  than  $10,000)  few  farms  of  any  type 
reported  as  much  as  $5,000  expended  for  hired  labor. 


Table  21. — Percentage  of  Farms  Reporting  $5,000  or  More 
Cash  Wages  Paid,  for  Each  Type  of  Commercial  Farm,  by 
Economic  Class,  for  the  United  States:  1954 


Total 

Economic  class  of  farm 

I 

n 

III 

rv 

V 

VI 

2.4 
1.2 
2.8 

1.5 
16.7 

14.7 
1.8 
1.7 

1.9 

3.8 
0.4 
1.0 
16.2 

40.2 
21.2 
70.8 
64.8 
88.0 

73.5 
61.5 
17.1 

21.2 

56.5 
28.5 
34.8 
77.9 

4.7 
1.1 
13.7 
10.9 
41.3 

22.8 
4.2 
1.0 

2  4 

7.6 

l  n 
2.2 

2K  2 

0.5 
0.2 
0.6 
0.4 
4.8 

3.5 
0.2 
0.2 

0.7 

0.8 
0.1 
0.3 
4.9 

0.2 
0.1 
(Z) 
(Z) 
0.9 

0.8 
(Z) 
0.2 

0.4 

0.2 
(Z) 
(Z) 
2.3 

(Z) 
(Z) 
(Z) 

(Z) 

m 

<7.) 

(7,) 

0.3 
(Z) 

0.1 

0.1 

Livestock  other  than  <lairy  and  poul- 

(7.) 

General: 

(Z) 
0.4 

Z     0.05  percent  or  loss. 


A  GENERAL  VIEW 


33 


Table  22.- 


-Percentage  Distribution  of  Commercial  Farms  in  Each  Type,  by  Economic  Class  of  Farm,  i 
for  Hired  Labor,  for  the  United  States:  1954 


Amount  of  Expenditure 


All  com- 
mercial 

Type  of  farm 

Economic  ebss  un.l  expenditure  for 
hired  labor 

Cash- 
grain 

Cotton 

fleld- 
crop 

Vege- 
table 

Fruit- 

Dairy 

Poultry 

Live- 
stock 

than 

dairy 

and 

poultry 

General — 

Pri- 
marily 
crop 

Pri- 
marily 

live- 
stock 

Crop 

live- 
stock 

Miscel- 
laneous 

100.0 
41.6 
45.8 
7.3 
3.0 

L4 
0.0 
0.4 

100.0 
7.0 
15.5 
18.3 
19.0 

40.2 
18.3 
13.2 
8.7 

100.0 
21.8 
42.2 
20.3 
11.1 

4.7 

(Z)' 

100.0 
34.3 
51.1 
11.6 
2.4 

0.5 

oil 

(Z) 

100.0 
41.6 
53.6 
4.1 

0.2 
0.1 

(Z) 

(Z) 

100.0 
51.1 
47.3 
1.3 
0.2 

(Z) 
(Z) 
(Z) 
(Z) 

100.0 
66.1 
33.4 
0.4 
0.1 

(Z) 
(Z) 
(Z) 

100.0 
45.1 
44.6 
6.8 
2.4 

1.2 
0.8 

100.  0 
6.4 
20.0 
27.5 
24.9 

21.2 
14.0 
5.2 
2.0 

100.0 
25.1 
52.2 

1.1 

0.9 

(Z)' 

100.0 
41.2 
62.8 
5.0 

0.2 
0.1 

(Z) 

(Z) 

100.0 
53.8 
43.6 

0^4 

0.1 
0.1 
(Z) 

100.  0 
39.0 
48.9 
6.5 
2.8 

2.8 

0.4 

100.0 
1.0 
3.3 

15' 9 

70.8 
31.0 
24.5 
15.3 

100.0 
4.5 
16.7 
29.7 
35.4 

13.7 

1.2 

(Z) 

100.0 
14.4 
42.0 
36.7 
6.4 

0.6 
0.5 
0.1 

100.0 
30.5 
60.7 
5.6 
1.7 

1.5 

0.4 
0.3 

100.0 
1.7 

10!  1 
16.5 

64.8 
27.0 
21.1 

16.7 

100.0 
5.3 
25.3 
34.5 
24.0 

10.9 
10.0 
0.9 
(Z) 

100.0 
11.1 
65.5 
20.2 
2.8 

0.4 
0.3 
0.1 

100.0 
24.8 
35.8 
14.3 
8.4 

16.7 
7.0 
5.1 
4.7 

100.  0 
0.3 
1.4 
3.9 
6.3 

88.0 
15.8 
32.0 
40.2 

100.0 
3.7 
8.9 
17.8 
28.3 

41.3 
32.3 
8.7 
0.3 

100.0 
11.9 
27.5 

17^6 

4.8 
4.2 
0.6 

100.0 
15.2 
39.8 
18.8 
11.4 

14.7 

7.8 

100.0 
2.1 

7l2 
14.2 

73.5 
27.3 
26.8 
19.4 

100.0 
4.6 
16.8 
25.4 
30.4 

22.8 
18.8 
3.9 
0.1 

100.0 
9.5 
36.2 
36.9 
13.9 

3.5 
3.0 
0.5 
(Z) 

100.  0 

69^9 
21.0 
3.5 

0.8 
0.6 
0.1 

100.0 
46.  0 
41.4 
7.8 
3.0 

1.8 
1.2 

0^2 

100.0 
4.5 
8.3 
13.6 
22.2 

61.5 
26.  7 
17.7 
7.1 

100.0 
18.9 
37.0 
26.1 
13.8 

4.2 
3.8 

100.0 
36.9 
50.6 
10.6 
1.8 

0.2 
(Z) 

100.0 
61. 1 
29.1 
5.5 
2.6 

1.7 
1.1 

6.1 

100.0 
19.6 
26.  3 
20.5 
16.5 

10!  8 
4.9 
1.5 

100.0 
41.5 
40.1 
12.8 
4.6 

1.0 
0.8 
0.1 

100.0 
43.1 
43.8 

3^2 

1.9 
1.2 
0.5 
0.2 

100.0 
9.5 
24.1 
24.5 
20.6 

21.2 
11.9 
6.1 
3.2 

100.0 
24.9 
48.6 
17.2 
6.9 

2.4 
2.0 
0.4 
(Z) 

100.0 
36.9 
51.9 
8.4 
2.2 

0.7 

oil 

(Z) 

100.0 

4&9 
4.9 
1.1 

0.4 
0.3 
0.1 
(Z) 

100.0 
54.6 
41.8 
2.8 
0.6 

0.1 
0.1 

(Z) 

(Z) 

100.0 
69.5 
29.3 
1.0 
0.2 

(Z) 

(Z) 
(Z) 

100.0 
32.1 
50.2 
9.6 
4.3 

3.8 
2.2 

0^7 

100.0 
3.6 
8.5 
13.2 
18.2 

56.5 
25.1 
15.8 
16.6 

100.0 
11.5 
33.4 
29.3 
18.3 

7.5 
6.6 

o!i 

100.0 
18.1 
67.9 
19.1 
4.2 

0.8 
0.6 
0.2 

100.0 
50.8 
44.1 
3.7 
0.9 

0.4 
0.3 
0.1 
(Z) 

100.0 
6.9 
18.9 
23.8 
21.8 

28.5 
14.7 
10.6 
3.2 

100.0 
26.9 
51.6 
16.2 

1.0 
0.9 
0.1 

100.0 

4&8 
5.5 
1.7 

o!i 

100.0 

is!  5 
21.5 
21.4 

34.8 

19.1 

100.0 
49!  1 

7^1 

2.2 
2.0 
0.2 
(Z) 

100.0 
37.8 
54.3 

1.0 

0.3 
0.2 

(Z) 

100.0 

36.8 

30.2 

10.4 

7.5 

6.6 

5.0 

3.5 

100.0 

3.9 

8.8 

77.9 

30.0 

29.0 

100.0 

12.5 

17.1 

19.2 

23.1 

28.2 

20.5 

7.6 

100.0 
56.1 
37.7 
4.8 
1.2 

0.2 
0.2 
(Z) 

100.0 
42.2 

52.8 

0^6 
6.1 

100.0 

20.9 

35.2 

20.2 

3.7 

29^9 
64.0 

0.3 

(Z) 

(Z) 

100.0 
21.4 
74.6 
3.7 
0.2 

(Z) 
(Z) 
(Z) 

100.0 

20!  0 

3.8 

0.9 
0.4 
0.5 

100.0 
51.1 
46.0 

6.3 

(Z) 
(Z) 
(Z) 

100.  0 

0^4 

0.2 
0.2 

(Z) 

(Z) 

100.0 
76.4 
22.7 
0.7 
0.1 

(Z) 

100.0 
28.8 
64.6 
5.5 
1.0 

0.2 
0.1 
0.1 

5£7 

45.9 

0^1 

(Z) 
(Z) 

100.  0 
43.7 

(Z) 
(Z) 

100.0 
64.1 
34.6 
1.0 
0.2 

(Z) 
(Z) 
(Z) 

100.0 
44.5 
55.0 
0.5 

(Z) 

(Z) 
(Z) 

100.0 

63^3 

0.7 
0.1 

(Z) 
(Z) 

100.0 
35.2 
57.9 
5.7 
1.2 

100.0 
26.2 
65.8 
6.2 
1.6 

0.3 
0.3 

100.0 
62.6 
36.6 
0.7 
0.1 

(Z) 
(Z) 

100.0 
43.0 
64.8 
1.8 
0.3 

0.1 
0.1 

(Z) 

100.0 
61.6 
37.9 
0.4 
0.1 

100.0 

47^4 

0.9 
0.2 

<Z) 
(Z) 

100.0 

40.7 

1.1 

(Z) 

100.0 
74.2 
25.1 
0.6 
0.2 

(Z) 

100.0 
58.6 
41.3 
0.1 

(Z) 

(Z) 

100.0 
57.8 
42.0 
0.2 

(Z) 

(Z) 
(Z) 

100.0 
57.6 
40.3 
1.7 
0.5 

100.0 
48.2 
47.7 
2.5 
1.4 

0.1 

100.0 
77.3 
22.6 
0.2 

(Z) 

100.0 
84.6 
14.9 
0.3 
0.1 

(Z) 
(Z) 

100.0 
65.6 
33.8 
0.3 
0.2 

100.0 
74.8 
24.9 
0.3 

100.0 
66.7 
32.9 
0.3 
0.1 

1OO.0 

(Z) 

(Z) 

0.1 

Z    0.05  percent  or  less. 


34 


Table  23. — Class  of  Work  Power:  Percentage  Distribution    of  Farms 

United  States:  1954 


FARMERS  AND  FARM  PRODUCTION 

Type  and  by  Specified  Economic  Classes,  for  the 


Total 

Economic  class  of 
farm 

Percentage  distribution  by  type  of  farm 

Total 

Economic  class  of 
farm 

1 

II,  III, 

and  IV 

Vand 
VI 

I 

II,  III, 

and  IV 

Vand 
VI 

100.0 
14.9 
14.0 
25.8 
45.3 

100.0 
6.3 
2.0 
22.0 
69.7 

100.0 
29.3 
29.1 
15.9 
25.7 

100.  0 

32^8 
26.1 
17.8 

100.0 
14.0 
11.2 
19.7 

55.1 

100.0 
28.8 
5.5 
10.5 
55.1 

100.0 
6.5 
8.1 
29.4 
55.9 

100.0 
6.9 
2.3 

54]  5 

100.0 
1.5 
0.4 
37.9 
60.1 

100.0 
1.7 
0.4 
37.1 
60.8 

100.0 
1.8 
1.5 

M.  6 

100.0 
2.8 
1.0 
24.2 
72.0 

100.0 
9.8 
0.7 
17.1 
72.4 

100.0 
6.8 
2.0 
39.2 
52.1 

100.0 
9.1 
6.3 
29.5 
55.1 

100.0 
3.9 

0.8 
22.5 
72.8 

100.0 
22.4 
12.7 
22.4 
42.5 

100.0 
17.6 
23.7 
35.2 
23.5 

100.0 
8.4 
4.6 
22.2 
64.8 

100.0 
27.1 
3.2 
10.3 
59.4 

100.0 
3.1 
3.8 
31.7 
61.4 

100.  0 
25.1 
27.6 
18.7 

100.0 
15.6 
6.3 
17.4 
60.7 

100.0 
34.7 
40.1 
11.0 
14.  1 

100.0 
29.4 
42.4 
17.2 

100.0 
24.2 
22.2 
15.2 

38.3 

100.0 
41.4 

12.7 
7.9 
38.0 

100.0 
15.1 
19.7 
23.0 
42.2 

Poultry 

100.0 
41.9 
11.2 
11.0 
35.8 

100.0 
8.8 
10.7 

44!  6 

100.0 
10.9 
13.2 
29.5 
46.4 

100.0 

9' 2 

28.8 
56.0 

100.0 
3.6 
7.8 
33.7 
54.9 

100.0 
37.9 
14.9 
18.3 
28.9 

100.0 
30.5 
4.3 
16.3 
48.9 

100.0 
2.3 
4.4 
49.0 
44.3 

100.0 
2.0 

0.4 
38.0 

100.0 
2.5 
0.3 
34.3 
62.8 

100.0 
1.1 
0.8 
46.0 
52.1 

100.0 
35.2 
2.2 
17.9 
44.8 

100.0 
38.5 
10.2 
12.3 
39.0 

100.0 
4.1 
4.8 
38.9 
52.2 

100.0 
6.4 
6.8 
34.6 
62.2 

100.0 
2.7 
4.3 
29.6 
63.4 

100.0 
2.2 
2.5 
34.4 
60.9 

100.0 
39.3 
9.3 
19.9 
31.5 

No  tractor,  and  1  or  more  liaises  and/or  mules 

No  tractor,  and  1  or  more  horses  and/or  mules 

No  tractor,  and  1  or  more  leases  and/or  mules 

No  tractor,  and  ]  or  moio  horses  and/or  mules 

No  tractor,  and  1  it  mure  horses  and  or  mules 

19.6 

No  tractor,  and  1  or  nunc  horses  :tn<l/or  mules 

No  tractor,  and  1  or  more  horses  and/or  mules 

No  tractor,  and  1  or  more  horses  and 'or  mules 

Class  of  Work  Power 

Some  indication  of  the  level  of  mechanization  practiced  by 
types  and  economic  classes  of  farms  may  be  gained  from  data  on 
class  of  work  power.  Tractors  are  more  common  to  some  parts 
of  commercial  agriculture  than  others  and  there  remains  con- 
siderable difference  in  the  extent  to  which  they  now  constitute 
the  sole  source  of  power. 

"Horseless  farming"  is  much  more  a  reality  on  cash-grain 
farms  than  most  other  types  (see  table  23).  Three-fifths  of  even 
the  smaller  economic  classes  of  farms  reported  a  tractor  and  no 
horses  or  mules. 

In  general,  Class  I  farms  of  each  type  are  highly  dependent 
on  tractors  as  the  only  source  of  power.  The  same  is  true  for 
Classes  II  through  IV  for  several  types;  namely,  cash-grain, 
vegetable,  fruit-and-nut,  dairy,  and  general  farms. 

Many  of  the  smaller  economic  classes  of  farms  had  neither 
tractors  nor  work  stock.  This  was  most  common  on  fruit-and-nut 
farms  and  poultry  farms.  It  was  also  common  on  cotton  and 
other  field-crop  farms,  largely  influenced  by  the  fairly  high  pro- 


portion  of  cropper  operators  included  in   the  smaller  economic 
classes. 

For  several  types  of  farms,  cash-grain,  dairy,  other  livestock, 
general  livestock,  and  general  crop  and  livestock  farms,  a  higher 
proportion  of  the  farms  in  Classes  II  through  IV  than  in  Class  I 
reported  tractors  and  no  work  stock. 

Land  in  Farms 

Of  the  total  land  area  in  the  United  States,  encompassing  about 
3  million  square  miles,  60.8  percent  is  in  farms.  In  1954,  the 
land  in  farms  totaled  1,158  million  acres  of  which  1,032.5  million 
acres,  or  89  percent,  was  in  commercial  farms. 

Nearly  half  of  the  land  in  commercial  farms  was  in  livestock 
farms  and  about  a  fifth  was  in  cash-grain  farms  (see  table  24). 
These  two  types,  which  comprise  37  percent  of  the  commercial 
farm  numbers,  accounted  for  more  than  two-thirds  of  the  land 
in  commercial  farms  in  1954.  If  general  livestock  and  general 
crop  and  livestock  farms  are  included,  the  proportion  of  the  land 
in  farms  of  the  livestock  and  cash-grain  types  exceeds  three-fourths 
of  the  land  in  all  commercial  farms. 


A  GENERAL  VIEW 


35 


Table  24. — Percent  Distribution  of  Total  Land  for  Each 
Economic  Class,  by  Type  of  Farm,  for  the  United  States: 
1954 


Typo  of  farm 

Total 

Economic  class  of  farm 

I 

II 

III 

IV 

V 

VI 

100.0 
19.8 
6.3 
3.3 
0.5 

0.9 
9.4 
1.2 

49.2 

LI 
5.2 
1.0 

100.0 
12.7 
6.0 
1.4 
0.9 

1.9 
2.3 
0.8 

69.6 

1.7 
0.2 
1.5 
1.0 

100.0 
25.6 

L5 
0.3 

0.8 
8.5 
1.1 

50.1 

1.9 
0.7 
4.6 
0.9 

100.0 
26.4 
4.2 
2.7 
0.2 

0.5 
13.4 
1.0 

39.8 

2.0 

1.5 
7.5 
0.7 

100.0 
20.6 

7.1 
5.5 
0.3 

0.0 
14.4 
1.2 

36.6 

2.4 
2.0 
8.5 

100.0 
13.6 
11.6 
7.5 

0.7 
12.7 
1.6 

39.1 

3.0 

2.0 
6.6 
1.4 

1 > 

9.0 

16.3 

8  ',' 

0.7 

Fruit-and-nut 

0.7 

10.4 

3.1 

Livestock  other  than  dairy  and  poul- 

41.2 

General: 

S  0 

l.G 

1.7 



The  distribution  of  land  in  farms  is  affected  by  the  different 
land  requirements  for  farms  in  different  parts  of  the  country. 
Many  of  the  livestock  and  cash-grain  farms  are  in  western  regions 
where,  because  of  limited  rainfall,  the  yields  of  crops  and  pastures 
are  low,  and  considerable  acreages  are  required  to  provide  an 
efficient  farm  organization.  On  many  western  livestock  farms 
20  or  more  acres  are  required  to  furnish  pasture  for  one  animal 
unit.  In  much  of  the  western  plains,  wheat  can  be  grown  only 
in  alternate  years.  Part  of  the  land  is  "fallowed"  each  year  to 
accumulate  enough  moisture  for  the  next  year's  crop. 

Although  less  than  10  percent  of  the  livestock  farms  are  in  the 
West,  these  comprise  40  percent  of  the  land  in  all  livestock  farms. 
The  western  region  contains  only  about  a  tenth  of  the  total 
number  of  cash-grain  farms,  but  a  fifth  of  the  land  in  such  farms 
is  in  the  western  region.  Similarly,  the  average  acreage  of  live- 
stock farms  in  the  West  is  several  times  the  acreages  in  northern 
and  southern  regions.  Cash-grain  farms  in  the  West  average 
more  than  twice  as  large  as  those  in  other  regions. 

Of  the  1,032  million  acres  of  land  in  commercial  farms  in  1954, 
25  percent  was  in  Class  I  farms,  about  60  percent  in  Classes  II, 
III,  and  IV,  and  slightly  less  than  15  percent  in  Class  V  and  VI 
farms  (see  table  25).  But  among  types  of  farms,  the  proportion 
of  the  commercial  farmland  by  economic  class  varies  considerably. 
Among  cash-grain  farms,  other  field-crop  farms,  dairy  farms, 
general  livestock,  and  general  crop  and  livestock  farms,  a  relatively 
small  proportion  of  the  farmland  is  contained  in  Class  I  farms. 
On  the  other  hand,  about  half  of  the  acreage  in  vegetable  and 
fruit-and-nut  farms  falls  in  Class  I  and  more  than  a  third  of  the 
land  in  livestock  farms. 

Of  all  land  in  Class  I  farms  more  than  two-thirds  is  in  livestock 
farms.  Cash-grain  farms  contain  about  13  percent  and  cotton 
farms  6  percent  of  the  acreage  in  all  Class  I  farms.  No  other  type 
accounts  for  as  much  as  3  percent  of  the  acreage  in  Class  I  farms. 

Nationally,  two-thirds  of  the  commercial  farms  and  three-fifths 
of  the  land  in  commercial  farms  are  in  Economic  Classes  II,  III, 
and  IV.  A  much  higher  proportion  of  the  acreage,  around  three- 
fourths,  is  found  in  these  classes  on  cash-grain,  dairy,  general 
livestock  and  general  crop  and  livestock  farms.  In  contrast,  less 
than  half  the  acreage  is  found  in  these  classes  on  cotton,  other 
field-crop,  vegetable,  and  fruit-and-nut  farms. 


The  land  contained  in  Economic  Classes  V  and  VI  ranged  from 
a  high  of  one-third  of  the  land  in  cotton  farms  to  a  low  of  9  percent 
for  cash-grain  farms. 


Table  25. — Percent  Distribution  of  Total  Land  in  Farms 
for  Each  Type  of  Commercial  Farm,  by  Economic  Class, 
for  the  United  States:  1954 


Total 

Economic  class  of  farm 

I 

II 

ni 

IV 

V 

VI 

100.0 

1110  II 

loo.o 

100.0 
100.0 

100.0 
100.0 

1 

100.0 

100.0 
100.0 
100.0 
100.0 

25.2 
16.1 
24.1 
11.1 
50.0 

49.4 
6.1 
17.8 
35.6 

20.2 
4.0 
7.3 

26.0 

23.4 
30.2 
14.8 
10.8 
13.1 

18.9 
21.1 
22.6 
23.8 

20.9 
15.5 
20.8 
21.8 

21.4 

28.6 
14.2 
17.5 
10.5 

12.1 
30.5 
18.9 
17.3 

20.3 
28.5 

:;o  i, 
14.9 

15.8 
16.4 
17.7 
26.8 
10.4 

9.3 
24.1 
15.7 
11.8 

17.9 

28.7 
25.6 
15.8 

9.9 
6.8 
18.3 
22.8 
9.1 

7.0 
13.4 

13.4 
7.9 

14.4 
17.3 
12.4 
14.0 

4  4 

11.1 

Vegetable 

Fruit-and-nut 

7.0 

3.3 

Livestock  uttier  than  dairy  and  poultry. 

General: 

Primarily  crop... --- 

Primarily  livestock 

3.6 

6.3 
6.0 
3.4 

Table  26  shows  the  average  acreage  per  farm  for  types  of  farms 
by  economic  class.  These  averages  disclose  the  wide  range  in 
acreage  found  within  each  economic  class  of  farm  and  the  variation 
by  type  of  farm.  Within  each  type  there  is  a  correlation  between 
size  measured  in  acres  and  size  measured  by  value  of  farm  products 
sold.  A  decrease  in  average  acreage  is  associated  with  a  decrease 
in  value  of  products  sold  for  each  type  of  farm.  This  relation  of 
acreage  to  value,  by  type  of  farm,  indicates  that  the  classification 
by  value  of  products  sold  provides  a  fairly  good  measure  of 
size  when  dealing  with  different  types  of  farms  under  widely 
different  production  conditions. 


Table  26. — Average  Size  of  Farm  For  Each  Type  of  Com- 
mercial Farm,  by  Economic  Class,  for  the  United  States: 
1954 


Total 

Economic  class  of  farm 

I 

II 

III 

IV 

V 

VI 

All  commercial  farms 

310.3 

3S0.  1 
124.4 
91.6 
146.6 

119.3 
177.2 
78.1 

730.7 

i-'.i  n 
264.7 
278.0 

1,939.1 

1,494.7 

1.031.6 

667.  5 

453.6 
508.4 
162.9 

4,539.0 

1,147.3 

773.1 

1,190.7 

597.1 

537.  8 

558.  9 
376  0 
236  5 
139.3 

120.6 

260  8 
94.9 

996.5 

452.3 

240.  0 
391.9 
385.1 

311.9 

363.  5 

106   7 

98!  1 

72.6 

ISO,  4 
79.7 

576.0 

303.6 
200.7 
202  (J 
276.5 

201.0 

260.  1 
99.3 
79.0 
78.0 

53.8 

152.5 

417.7 

190.5 
177.9 
234.1 
228.6 

134.3 
167.  9 
63.8 
65.7 
66.9 

43.0 
126.3 
55.9 

291.3 

147.0 
145.1 
161. 1 
172.1 

97.1 
121.8 

54.1 

64.5 

52.4 

1'nnt-and-nut 

46.8 
97.8 

51.3 

Livi-tork    oilier    than    dairy 
and  poultry 

General: 

183.6 
128.6 

106.3 

121.6 

136.8 

36 


FARMERS  AND  FARM  PRODUCTION 


The  average  acreage  per  farm,  however,  tends  to  conceal  the 
extreme  variations  in  acreage  that  exist  within  each  economic 
class.  Table  27  shows  the  frequency  distribution  of  the  number 
of  farms  grouped  by  acreage  size  for  each  type  of  farm  by  economic 
class.  Although  the  average  acreage  of  land  for  Class  I  farms  was 
more  than  1,000  acres  for  cash-grain,  cotton,  livestock,  general 
crop,  and  general  crop  and  livestock  farms,  most  of  the  farms  are 
considerably  smaller.  More  than  half  of  the  Class  I  farms  in 
each  of  these  types  have  from  220  to  999  acres.  A  majority  of 
Class  I  vegetable  and  fruit-and-nut  farms  have  less  than  220 
acres,  and  more  than  half  of  the  Class  I  poultry  farms  have  less 
than  100  acres.  Half  of  the  Class  I  farms  of  under  10  acres  were 
poultry  farms  in  1954.  Nearly  half  of  the  Class  I  farms  of  1,000 
or  more  acres  were  livestock  farms  and  almost  a  third  were  cash- 
grain  farms. 

Among  farms  in  the  median  range  in  value  of  products  sold 
(Classes  II,  III,  and  IV),  certain  acreage-size  groups  tend  to  pre- 
dominate. Most  of  the  cash-grain,  livestock,  and  general  farms 
in  Classes  II,  III,  and  IV,  are  in  the  groups  between  100  and  500 


acres.  Cotton  and  other  field-crop  farms  are  heavily  concentrated 
in  the  acreage-size  groups  between  10  and  220  acres.  Over  half 
of  the  dairy  farms  fall  in  the  size  group  between  100  and  220  acres, 
while  a  majority  of  poultry  and  fruit-and-nut  farms  have  less  than 
50  acres. 

A  higher  proportion  of  Economic  Classes  V  and  VI  are  in  the 
smaller  acreage  groups  for  each  type  of  farm.  However,  the 
relationship  between  acreage  and  value  of  sales  is  not  so  direct  as 
might  be  expected.  For  each  type  of  farm,  except  cash-grain 
farms,  the  modal  acreage-size  group  (the  one  containing  the  largest 
number  of  farms)  is  the  same  for  Class  V  and  VI  farms  as  for 
Classes  II,  III,  and  IV.  This  indicates  the  wide  variation  in  the 
quality  of  land  and  the  proportion  that  is  suitable  for  growing 
crops  and  grasses  even  among  farms  of  basically  the  same  type  of 
farming.  It  is  also  related  to  differences  in  the  extent  to  which 
these  groups  of  farmers  have  taken  advantage  of  new  techniques 
that  are  aimed  to  increase  yields  per  crop  acre  and  per  animal 
unit. 


Table  27.— Number  of  Farms  in  Specified  Acreage-Size  Groups  for  Each  Type  of  Commerical  Farm  by  Economic  Ci 

United  States:  1954 


Number  of  farms  by  type 


Kcunnloie  class   Oct  acreage  si/. 


other 
field- 
crop 


Live- 
stock 
other 

dairy  or 

poultry 


Primarily  Plj'™'ily  V '"'. '„:"ul 
cr°P  stock  stock 


All  classes. 

Under  10  acres 

10  to  49  acres 

50  to  99  acres 


3,  327, 
145.  400 

022.  021 


525,403 
20.  10-1 
230,  11'. 

(i  i  r., ;)'.)'. 


307.7.;.: 
31.721 

143,547 
1.10,270 


37,057 
11,200 
li,  837 
4,184 


100  to  219  acres.. 
220  to  499  acres.. 
500  to  999  acres. 


Class  I... 

Under  lo  acres 
10  to  49  acres. 
50  to  99  acres  . 


44,  144 
13,120 

6,  895 


13,  137 

2,  102 

3.  202 
2,010 


2,805 
3,784 


1,01)0  acres  and  over. 


100  to  219  acres. 
220  to  499  acres. 
600  to  999  acres. 
1,000  acres  and  0 


Classes  V  and  VI. 
Under  10  acre: 
10  to  49  acres. 
50  to  99  acres . 


19.  127 
40,  1110 
21.MI7 


41,  451 

225, 573 
270,510 


133.  O00 
153,251 
53,  704 


5.  5V.I 
4,503 
3,  570 


50,  310 
2\  S03 

7,479 
2,144 


1  5,  05S 

710 

6,891 

3,  7S5 


48,  573 
1,000 

21'.,  075 
9,  131 


22.  Ms 
6,515 

11.005 
2,871 


5S0.270 
1,104 
15,  474 

07,001 


84.741 

20,330 
21,501 
17, '240 


61,  701 

IS.  3H0 
11,520 


18.4S3 
0,  04!'. 
3,265 
1,536 


14,003 
2,000 
2,  382 
2,271 


loo  to  210  acres 

220  t..  too  acres 

500  to  009  acres 

1,000  acres  and  over.. 


70,  100 
44,  701 
11,  400 

8,  273 


A  GENERAL  VIEW 


37 


Cropland  Harvested 

About  322  million  acres  were  in  harvested  crops  in  1954.  This 
was  slightly  less  than  a  third  of  the  total  land  in  farms.  The 
proportion  of  the  land  that  was  in  harvested  crops  varied  among 
types  of  farms  and  between  economic  classes  within  each  type 
(see  table  28).  Approximately  half  or  more  of  the  total  land  was 
in  harvested  crops  on  cash-grain,  cotton,  vegetable,  and  general 
farms.  Between  a  third  and  two-fifths  of  the  land  in  other  field- 
crop,  fruit-and-nut,  and  dairy  farms,  was  harvested  cropland — 
only  a  fourth  of  the  land  in  poultry  farms  and  15  percent  of  the 
land  in  livestock  farms. 


Table  28. — Cropland  Harvested  As  A  Percent  of  Total 
Land  in  Farms  for  Each  type  of  Farm,  by  Economic  Class 
of  Farm,  for  the  United  States:  1954 


Type  of  farm 

Total 

Economic  class  of  farm 

I 

n 

in 

IV 

V 

VI 

31.1 
54.5 
50.6 
36.3 
46.9 

37.0 
38.1 
26.0 

15.4 

41.6 
46.8 
47.0 
8.2 

18.8 
47.5 
54.3 
49  1 
51.4 

36.2 

:;■_■  i] 
30.6 

7.5 

46.7 
31.0 
35.6 

in  ■_' 

35.8 
57.8 

57.1 
48.1 
54.5 

41.9 
42.7 
28.7 

19.4 

47.6 
58.4 
53.4 
7.1 

40.0 
58.2 
54.7 
40.6 
47.3 

41.5 
42.2 
26.8 

23.3 

42.2 

M   .', 

7!  4 

54.1 
52.4 
36.4 
39.5 

35.4 
37.9 
25.6 

20.5 

40.6 
46.3 
45.9 
7.8 

28.7 
47.2 
45.8 
28.5 
33.5 

30.6 
30.2 
22.7 

15.4 

33.8 
35.7 
36.7 
7.7 

Fruit-and-nut 

23.2 

Livestock    other    than    dairy    and 

General: 

For  most  types  of  farms  the  larger  farms  and  the  smaller  farms 
have  less  of  the  land  in  harvested  crops.  This  results  in  a  slightly 
higher  proportion  of  the  cropland  than  of  the  total  land  being 
found  among  the  medium-sized  Classes  II,  III,  and  IV  farms. 
Four-fifths  or  more  of  the  cropland  is  accounted  for  by  these 
classes  for  cash-grain,  dairy,  general  livestock,  and  general  crop 
and  livestock  farms  (see  table  29).  Half  or  more  of  the  cropland 
is  found  on  Classes  II,  III,  and  IV  farms  for  each  of  the  other 
types,  with  the  exception  of  vegetable  and  fruit-and-nut  farms. 
For  these  two  types,  half  or  more  of  the  cropland  is  in  Class  I 
farms.  About  70  percent  is  accounted  for  by  Classes  I  and  II 
together.  Economic  Classes  V  and  VI  account  for  a  smaller 
proportion  of  the  cropland  than  of  the  total  land  in  farms  for 
each  type  of  farm. 

Cash-grain  farms  and  livestock  farms  accounted  for  a  third  and 
a  fourth,  respectively,  of  the  harvested  cropland  (see  table  30). 
Cotton  farmers  and  dairy  farmers  each  used  about  a  tenth  of  the 
cropland.  With  the  exception  of  general  crop  and  livestock  farms 
which  accounted  for  8  percent  of  the  cropland,  no  other  type 
accounted  for  as  much  as  4  percent.  Cash-grain  farms  and  live- 
stock farms  taken  together  accounted  for  more  than  half  of  the 
cropland  harvested  in  each  Economic  Classes  I  through  IV  and 
two-fifths  of  the  cropland  in  Class  V  and  Class  VI  farms.  On 
Class  VI  farms,  however,  a  higher  proportion  of  the  cropland 
was  accounted  for  by  cotton  farms. 

The  average  acreage  of  cropland  harvested  per  farm  is  largest  on 
cash-grain  farms  and  lowest  on  poultry  farms  (see  table  31). 
Except  for  cash-grain  farms,  livestock  farms  and  general  crop  and 
livestock  farms  had  a  larger  average  acreage  in  crops  harvested 
than  any  of  the  types  that  had  a  major  source  of  income  from  sales 
of  crops. 


Table  29. — Percent  Distribution  of  Total  Acreage  of 
Cropland  Harvested  for  Each  Type  of  Commercial  Farm 
by  Economic  Class,  for  the  United  States:  1954 


Total 

Economic  class  of  farm 

I 

II 

III 

IV 

v 

VI 

All  commercial  farms 

100.0 
100.0 
100.0 
100.0 
100.0 

100.0 
100.0 
100.0 

100.0 

100.0 

inn  n 
100.0 
100.0 

15  2 

un 
2.V  * 
15.0 
54.8 

48.3 
5.1 
20.9 

17.  1 

22.6 
2.7 
5.5 

32.2 

26.9 

16.7 

14.3 
15.2 

21.4 

:•:;.  7 
24.8 

29.9 

23  9 

19.3 
23.6 
19.0 

27.4 
30.4 
16.3 

in.  i; 

10.6 

13.6 
33.8 

19.5 

26.1 

20.6 

:;;;  2 
34.3 
13.4 

18.4 
10.3 
18.3 
26.8 
8.8 

8.9 
24.0 
15.5 

15.6 

17.5 
28.4 
25.0 
15.0 

9.1 
5.9 
16.5 
17.9 

6.5 

6.7 
10.6 
11.7 

7.9 

11.7 
13.2 
9.7 
13.2 

3.0 

7.4 

1  r.iit  and 

•>,  8 

Livestock    other    than    dairy    and 

3.0 

General: 

3,2 

1.9 

Table  30. — Percent  Distribution  of  Total  Acreage  of 
Cropland  Harvested  for  Each  Economic  Class,  by  Type 
of  Farm,  for  the  United  States:  1954 


Total 

Economic  class  of  farm 

I 

II 

III 

IV 

V 

VI 

All  commercial  farms 

100.0 
34.7 
10.3 
3.8 
0.7 

1.1 
11.5 
1.0 

24.3 

2.8 
1.7 
7.9 
0.3 

loo.o 

31.9 
17.4 
3.8 
2.5 

3.6 

3.9 
1.3 

27.8 

4.1 
0.3 
2.9 
0.6 

100.0 
41.4 
6.4 
2.0 
0.4 

0.9 
10.1 
0.9 

27.1 

2.5 
1.2 
6.9 
0.2 

inn  n 
38.6 
5.7 
2.7 
0.3 

0.6 
14.2 
0.7 

23.2 

2.1 
2.0 
9.9 
0.1 

100.0 
30.7 
10.2 
5.5 
0.3 

0.5 
15.0 
0.8 

20.7 

2.6 
2.6 

10.7 
0.2 

100.0 

22.3 
18.6 
7.6 
0.5 

0.7 
13.4 
1.2 

21.0 

3.6 
2.4 
8.4 
0.4 

100.0 
15.6 

8.(1 

1.0 

0  8 

10.8 

2.5 

Livestock  other  than  dairy  and  poul- 

24.5 

General: 

3  5 

5.1 

0.6 

Table  31. — Average  Acreage  of  Cropland  Harvested  per 
Farm  for  Each  Type  of  Commercial  Farm,  by  Economic 
Class,  for  the  United  States:  1954 


Total 

Economic  class  of  farm 

I 

II 

III 

rv 

V 

VI 

102 
207 

33 

69 

44 
67 
20 

113 

112 
86 
124 

23 

398 
710 
560 
329 
327 

164 
163 
60 

341 

536 
246 
426 
61 

201 
323 
215 

76 

61 
115 
27 

193 

215 
146 
209 
27 

129 
211 

ION 

50 
46 

21 
134 

128 
110 
154 

20 

76 
141 
52 
29 
31 

19 
58 
18 

86 

77 

107 

18 

41 
79 
29 
19 
22 

13 
38 
13 

45 

50 
52 
59 
13 

18 

15 

11 

Livestock  other  than  dairy  and  poul- 
try  

General: 

Primarily  crop.. 

Primarily  livestock 

23 

31 

26 

II 

38 


FARMERS  AND  FARM  PRODUCTION 


Value  of  Land  and  Buildings 

Differences  in  the  land — its  quality,  productiveness,  and  loca- 
tion, the  proportion  suitable  for  crops,  and  the  improvements  made 
to  the  land — are  reflected  in  the  average  values  per  acre.  Table  32 
shows  the  average  value  of  land  and  buildings  per  acre  for  each 
type  of  farm  by  economic  class.  The  liighest  value  per  acre  for 
any  type  of  farm  is  for  fruit-and-nut  farms.  This  is  true  when 
comparison  is  made  within  each  economic  class.  Relatively  high 
values  per  acre  are  also  shown  for  vegetable  farms  and  poultry 
farms. 


Table  32. — Average  Value  per  Acre  of  Land  and  Buildings 
for  Each  Type  of  Commercial  Farm,  by  Economic  Class, 
for  the  United  States:  1954 


All  commercial  farms. 

Cash-grain 

Cotton... 

Other  field-crop 

Vegetable 

Fruit-and-nut 

Dairy 

Poultry 

Livestock  other  than  dairy 
poultry 

General: 

Primarily  crop 

Primarily  livestock 

Crop  and  livestock 

Miscellaneous 


!:<•_'.  2S 
105.34 
174.  T2 


n:i  ■■:, 
in;  :.v 
96.58 

I  I  2  lis 


Kcononiic  class  of  farm 


73.30 
108.96 
175. 10 

r-u  mi 

2V9.  05 

:«2.  21 
194.23 
210.45 


17:;.  v.i 
122.12 
117.54 

171.21 


-.11   111 
134.52 

i:u  '.i7 


I'.i:,  iv 
107.  26 
167.  77 


84.46 
73.54 
88.76 
176.  61 

412  71 
70.93 

li'.l   79 


2i;o  r,r, 

61.60 

118.95 
51.23 


On  fruit-and-nut  farms  the  land  value  reflects  the  substantial 
investment  in  orchards,  vineyards,  and  planted  nut  trees.  Both 
fruit-and-nut  and  vegetable  farms  are  highly  specialized  types 
which  require  fairly  exacting  soil  and  climatic  conditions.  Many 
are  in  areas  that  have  access  to  irrigation  and  irrigation  facilities. 
Water  rights  tend  to  be  reflected  in  land  values.  Many  vegetable 
farms  are  in  low-lying  tracts  that  have  been  reclaimed  and  drained 
at  considerable  expense  per  acre.  Poultry  farms  reflect  the  large 
investment  in  buildings,  to  house  and  care  for  laying  hens  and 
broilers,  associated  with  a  relatively  small  acreage. 

The  lowest  values  per  acre  are  found  on  livestock  farms.  These 
values  are  influenced  by  the  large  number  of  cattle  ranches  in 
semiarid  western  regions  which  have  large  acreages  with  a  low 
carrying  capacity  per  animal  unit. 

Values  per  acre  tend  to  decrease  with  decreasing  size  as  measured 
by  gross  sales.  The  exception  is  noticeable  among  Class  I  farms. 
For  about  half  of  the  types,  the  values  per  acre  on  Class  II  farms 
exceed  those  on  Class  I  farms. 

The  distribution  of  the  value  of  land  and  buildings  among  types 
of  farms  is  more  nearly  equal  than  the  distribution  by  economic 
class,  for  there  is  a  tendency  for  types  of  farms  with  smaller 
acreage  requirements  to  have  land  of  higher  value  (see  table  33). 
But  within  each  type  of  farm  a  greater  concentration  of  value 
than  of  acreage  is  shown  for  the  larger  economic  classes. 

The  average  value  of  land  and  buildings  per  commercial  farm 
was  greatest  on  cash-grain  and  fruit-and-nut  farms  and  lowest  on 
cotton,  other  field-crop,  and  poultry  farms  (see  table  34).  On 
each  type  of  farm  the  average  value  of  land  and  buildings  per  farm 
increases  directly  with  increasing  size  of  farm  as  measured  by  gross 
sales.  The  range  of  value  is  from  less  than  $10,000  per  farm  on 
Class  VI  farms  to  more  than  $100,000  per  farm  on  Class  I  farms. 
But  among  farms  in  each  economic  class  there  are  considerable 
differences  in  value. 


Table  33. — Percent  Distribution  of  Value  of  Land  and  Buildings   by  Type 
Farms,  for  the  United  States:  1954 


^nd   Economic  Class  of  Commercial 


Total 

Economic  class  of  farm 

I 

II 

III 

IV 

V 

VI 

Percent  distribution  in  each  type  of  farm  by  economic  class: 

100.0 

100.0 
100.0 
100.0 
100.0 

100.0 

ioo.o 

100.0 
100.0 

100.0 
100.0 
100.0 
100.0 

100.0 

23.3 
8.0 

4.5 
1.3 

4.2 
13.2 

2.5 
31.1 

2.7 

6^3 
1.2 

22.2 
17.1 
37.1 
lfi.8 
54.6 

45.0 
11.2 
21.5 
24.2 

30.7 
4.5 
8.9 

38.6 

100.0 
18.0 
13.3 
3.4 

9.0 
6.5 
2.5 
35.1 

3.7 
0.3 
2.5 
2.2 

27.4 
34.8 
18.0 
14.0 
16.4 

22.4 
26.8 
25.2 
28.5 

23.5 
22.1 

22!  7 

100.0 
29.4 
5.2 
2.4 
0.8 

3.5 
12.9 

2.3 
32.6 

2.3 
1.3 
6.3 
1.0 

23,  2 

27.6 

IO 
10.9 

19.9 
30.8 
18.2 
21.0 

17.3 
33.1 
31.6 
13.2 

100.0 
27.6 
4.6 
3.8 
0.6 

2.5 
17.4 

1.8 
28.1 

2.0 
2.2 

8.6 
0.7 

16.1 
13.4 
13.9 
25.7 

9.6 

14.3 

13.5 

13.9 
24.1 
20.4 
11.1 

100.0 
20.9 

0^8 

2.6 
16.9 
2.2 
7.3 

2.5 
2.6 
8.5 
0.9 

8.8 
5.6 
11.9 
17.1 
6.1 

7.1 
8.9 
12.7 
8.9 

10.8 
12.4 
9.1 
10.3 

100.0 
15.0 
11.6 
8.6 
0.9 

3.3 
13.3 

3.4 
30.6 

3.3 
2.1 

6.5 
1.4 

3.3 

6.6 

3.6 

2.0 

2.8 

8.0 

3.8 

General: 

Primarily  crop 

Primarily  livestock 

Crop  and  livestock 

Miscellaneous 

Percent  distribntion  in  each  economic  class  of  farm  by  type: 

All  commercial  farms 

Cash-grain 

Cotton 

Other  field-crop 

Vegetablo 

Fruit-and-nut 

Dairy 

Poultry 

Livestock  other  than  dairy  and  poultry 

General: 

Primarilv  crop _ 

Primarily  livestock 

Crop  and  livestock 

Miscellaneous 

3.7 
3.8 
2.1 
4.1 

100.0 
10.3 
14.5 

8.9 
1.5 

2.6 
10.9 

5.7 
35.2 

3.0 
1.7 
4.1 
1.6 

A  GENERAL  VIEW 


39 


-Average   Value   of   Investment   in   Land   and  Buildings,  Livestock  Inventory,  Machinery,  and  Total  Invest' 
ment  for  Each  Type  of  Commercial  Farm,  by  Economic  Class,  for  the  United  States:  1954 


and  type,  of  farm 


nd  buildings  per  farm: 

commercial  farms  

<  'asli-cnnu 

Cotton 

Other  iii'ld-CTOp 

Vegetable 


Fruit-and-nut 

Dairy 

Poultry 

Livestock  other  than  dairy  and  poult r 


General: 

Primarily  erop 

Primarily  livestock. 

Crop  and  livestock., 
M  isoellai is 


All  commercial  I 

Cash-grain. 

Cotton 

Other  field-crop.. 
Vegetable 


Fruit-and-nut 

Dairy 

Poultry... 

Livestock  other  than  dairy  and  poultry. 


General: 

Primarily  crop 

Primarily  hvestoek 
Crop  and  livestock. 


Miscellaneous  . 


All  commercial  (arms. 

Cash-grain. 

Cotton... 

Other  field-crop. 
Vegetable 


Fruit-and-nut 

Dairy 

Poultry 

Livestock  other  than  dairy  and  poultr. 


Primarily  crop 

Primarily  livestock. 

Crop  and  livestock . 

Miscellaneous 

Total  investment  per  farm : 

All  commercial  farms 

Cash-grain. 

Cotton. 

Other  field-crop 

Vegetable 

Fruit-and-nut 

Dairy. 

Poultry 

Livestock  other  tha 


dairy  and  poultry. 


General: 

Primarily  crop 

Primardy  livestock 
Crop  and  livestock  . 

Miscellaneous 


Total  investment  per  farm: 

All  commercial  farms 

Cash-grain. 

Cotton , 

Other  field-crop 

Vegetable 

Fruit-and-nut 

Poultr"7-l----  ------------------  ----- 

Livestock  other  than  dairy  and  poultry 

General: 

Primarily  crop 

Primarily  livestock 

Crop  and  livestock 

Miscellaneous 


Kcooomic  class  of  faun 


.1*      I 


Average  value  (d 

ollars) 

28,  429 

III.IM 
12,970 
10,44(1 
38,327 

134, 169 

163,664 
171,142 
109,421 
192, 184 

51,510 
67, 673 
49,386 
34,934 

27,992 
37, 193 
20.  700 
16,071 
25,699 

15,880 
22, 397 
8,593 
8,788 
16,490 

9,829 
14,402 
4,570 
5,727 
11,334 

46,252 
is,  .Mil 

3C.!::ii3 

162,497 
9ft,  312 
33,754 

142,449 

66,  059 
35, 751 
18,041 
58, 179 

33,462 
20, 122 
13, 091 
34,  774 

23,021 

12.960 

111,  Mill 

23,895 

18,071 
8,977 
9,347 

16,541 

29,25)6 

1!'.  Mil'. 
25,  499 
28,  033 

84!  375 
128,384 
85,411 

55,169 
39,913 
50,626 
40,345 

28,682 
24,669 
29,421 
25,416 

15,998 
15,944 
18,109 
17,038 

12,280 

1L440 
13,624 

3,154 

2,  279 

844 

761 

871 

15,021 
6,421 
5,074 
3,918 
3,054 

5, 986 
3,606 
2,031 
2,269 
850 

3,697 
2,479 
1,264 
1,206 
737 

2,178 

1,559 

795 

685 

589 

1,327 

851 
551 
527 
491 

697 
3, 434 
1,537 
7,520 

2,560 
15,039 

4,068 
35,327 

740 
6,  034 
2,261 
11,544 

450 
3,872 
1,551 
7,197 

321 
2,634 
1,197 

248 
1,801 

877 
3,162 

1,741 
3,451 
3,  496 
1,207 

7,290 
13, 502 
15,  726 

2,376 

3.  312 
6,320 
6,  124 

1,537 

2.094 
4.374 
4,101 
1,280 

1,307 
3,029 

l!  125 

790 
2,058 
1,760 

808 

4,291 

6,  393 
2, 091 
1,991 
0,016 

15,649 
19,323 
18,768 
19,337 
24,260 

8,444 
9,738 
7,231 
7,461 
8,036 

5,304 

3J488 
3,039 
4,711 

3,  232 
4,588 
1,679 
1,655 
3,289 

L025 
1,144 
2,309 

4,641 

4,528 
2.  4111'. 
6,338 

14,433 
15,302 
6,394 
14,058 

6,871 
8,635 
3,502 
8,937 

3,544 
6,150 
2,519 
6,062 

3,' 481 
1,992 
4,180 

1,955 
2,421 
1,625 
2,829 

4,835 

4,336 
ft,  136 
3,  94(1 

22, 092 
15,203 
19,  745 
11,381 

9,442 
8,385 

9,098 
5,  491 

5,  410 
ft,  666 
6,056 
3,615 

3,209 
3,644 

4,168 
2,808 

2,280 

2,535 
2,671 
1,915 

32,874 

IS, 736 
15,914 
13,192 
45,  214 

164,839 
189, 408 
194,984 
132,  676 
219,498 

65,  940 
81,017 
58,648 
44,664 
53,708 

36,993 
46,052 
25,452 
20,316 
31, 147 

21,290 
28,544 
11,067 
11,128 
20,368 

13,155 
18,381 
6,146 
7,398 
14, 134 

51,  590 

2i'.,  163 
17.923 
49,  221 

179,490 
125,653 
44,216 
191,834 

61,670 

50, 420 
23,804 
78,660 

37,456 
29,144 
17, 161 
48,033 

25,771 
19, 075 
14,079 
32,935 

20,274 
13, 199 
11,849 
22,532 

35, 872 
27.  I..S3 
34, 131 
33, 180 

219,573 
111,080 
163,855 
99,168 

S-jUiS 
65,848 
47, 373 

36, 186 
34,709 
39,  578 
30,311 

20,  514 
22,  617 
25,049 
20,971 

15,360 

15,982 
15,877 
16,347 

lYio.'iti  il^tribtition 


40 


FARMERS  AND  FARM  PRODUCTION 


Value  of  Livestock 

The  value  of  livestock  on  farms  was  ascertained  by  multiplying 
the  numbers  of  each  kind  of  livestock  and  poultry  by  the  average 
values  per  head.  Except  for  regional  differentials  in  values  per 
head,  the  computed  values  assume  equal  value  per  head  among 
livestock  and  poultry  for  each  type  and  class  of  farm. 

The  value  of  livestock  per  farm  is  much  greater  on  those  types 
with  a  major  source  of  income  from  sales  of  livestock  and  livestock 
products.  Livestock  were  valued  at  more  than  $7,000  on  other 
livestock  farms  and  at  more  than  $3,000  on  dairy,  general  livestock, 
and  general  crop  and  livestock  farms.  A  relatively  small  invest- 
ment in  livestock  is  shown  for  types  of  farms  that  have  a  major 
source  of  sales  from  crops. 

Estimated  Value  of  Machinery 

To  give  a  more  complete  picture  of  the  total  investment  on 
farms,  the  value  of  machinery  was  estimated  for  each  type  and 
economic  class.  The  total  value  of  machinery  and  equipment  on 
farms  for  the  United  States  (as  estimated  by  the  Agricultural 
Marketing  Service  and  the  Agricultural  Research  Service,  U.  S. 
Department  of  Agriculture)  was  used  as  an  overall  guide.  The 
U.  S.  Department  of  Agriculture  estimated  the  value  of  machinery 
and  equipment  on  farms  at  $15.9  billion  in  1954,  of  which  $3.7 
billion  was  in  automobiles,  $1.9  billion  in  motortrucks,  $3.2  billion 
in  tractors,  and  $7.2  billion  in  other  machinery  and  equipment. 
This  value  was  distributed  among  types  and  economic  classes  of 
farms  on  the  basis  of  numbers  of  automobiles,  trucks,  tractors, 
and  other  specified  items  of  machinery  reported  by  the  1954 
Census  of  Agriculture. 

Each  item  of  farm  equipment  reported  by  the  Census  was  as- 
signed a  weighting  factor  equivalent  to  its  average  new  retail  price. 
These  factors  were  adjusted  to  reflect  differences  in  age  of  machines 
on  the  basis  of  age  differentials  reported  for  automobiles,  trucks, 
and  tractors,  by  economic  class  in  the  Census  of  1950.  The  ad- 
justment made  for  age  of  machine  is  shown  below.  The  age 
differential  for  tractors  was  applied  to  the  weighting  factor  for 
each  item  of  tractor  equipment. 


Economic  class 

Automobiles 

Trucks 

Tractors 

(Index,  commercial  farms=  100) 

100 
156 
140 
117 
93 
77 
61 
82 

100 
136 
119 
99 
94 
92 
84 
98 

Department  of  Agriculture  that  relates  size  of  tractor  in  belt  horse- 
power to  acreage  size  of  farm.3  The  weighting  factor  for  each 
item  except  automobiles  was  adjusted  by  the  index  that  is  shown 
below. 

Index  of 
values  (all 
Acreage  size  farms=100) 


The  factors  were  then  adjusted  to  further  reflect  a  size  of  ma- 
chine differential  for  each  type  and  economic  class  as  related  to 
the  average  acreage  in  farms.  An  index  of  value  differentials  by 
acreage  size  of  farm  was  computed  from  a  report  by  the  U.  S. 


All  farms 

Under  100  acres 

100  to  199  acres 

200  to  399  acres 

400  to  599  acres 

600  to  999  acres 

1,000  acres  and  over. 


100 

85 

92 

100 

104 

108 

112 

The  appropriate  weighting  factors,  as  adjusted  for  age  and  size 
of  machine,  were  multiplied  by  the  number  of  each  specified  ma- 
chine. The  product  was  then  adjusted  to  agree  with  the  estimate 
by  the  U.  S.  Department  of  Agriculture  of  value  for  the  United 
States  of  automobiles,  separately,  and  of  all  other  machinery  and 
equipment.  Of  the  total  value  of  machinery  and  equipment  on 
farms  in  1954,  it  was  estimated  that  $14,280  million  (90  percent) 
was  on  commercial  farms. 

The  average  investment  per  commercial  farm  in  machinery  and 
equipment  ranges  from  less  than  $2,000  on  cotton  and  other  field- 
crop  farms  to  more  than  $6,000  on  cash-grain  and  vegetable  farms. 
By  economic  class,  the  range  is  from  $1,000  on  Class  VI  farms  to 
more  than  $15,000  on  Class  I  farms. 

There  are  even  greater  differences  between  economic  classes  of 
farms  for  certain  types  of  farms.  Class  VI  cotton  and  other  field- 
crop  farms  were  estimated  to  have  an  investment  in  machinery  of 
about  $600  compared  with  nearly  $20,000  on  Class  I  farms  for 
these  types.  On  the  smaller  economic  classes  of  cotton  and  other 
field-crop  farms,  however,  the  value  of  investment  in  machinery 
and  equipment  is  somewhat  incomplete  because  of  the  inclusion 
of  cropper  farms.  Croppers  are  particularly  numerous  among 
these  types.  It  is  customary  for  most  of  the  machinery  used  on 
cropper  farms  to  be  owned  by  the  landlord  and  kept  on  his  "home 
farm."  For  landlords  who  farm  on  a  commercial  scale,  their 
home  farms  are  likely  to  fall  in  larger  economic  classes  than  do 
the  individual  cropper  units. 

The  range  in  machinery  value  between  economic  classes  of 
poultry  farms  is  much  less  than  among  the  other  types  of  farms. 
It  ranges  upward  from  $1,000  on  Class  VI  farms  to  $6,000  on  Class 
I  farms.  The  items  of  equipment  used  for  estimating  value  of 
machinery  are  basically  field-crop  equipment.  As  such,  they  are 
probably  less  representative  of  equipment  used  on  poultry  farms 
than  of  most  other  types.  Values  of  machinery  estimated  for 
the  larger  economic  classes  of  poultry  farms  are  lower  than  for 
similar  classes  among  other  types.  This  may  be  affected  some- 
what by  the  procedure  for  estimating  value.  But  values  shown 
do  not  appear  unreasonable  in  view  of  the  somewhat  different 
nature  of  capital  investment  on  poultry  farms.  Much  of  the 
machinery  is  used  as  installations  in  poultry  housing  and  becomes 
incorporated  into  the  value  of  land  and  buildings.  The  same  is 
probably  true  of  dairy  farms  also. 


i  Br.i.icll,  Albert,  aw]  Kcii'l.ill,  Albert  R.,  Fuel  and  Motor  Oil  Consumption  and  Annuo!  Use  of  Farm  Tractors,  FM-72,  BAE,  1'SDA, 


A  GENERAL  VIEW 


41 


Total  Value  of  Investment 

Total  values  of  farm  investment  are  always  of  interest.  When 
the  investment  in  land  and  buildings,  livestock,  and  machinery 
are  combined,  the  total  investment  per  commercial  farm  was 
nearly  $33,000  in  1954.  Highest  investment  per  commercial 
farm  is  shown  for  cash-grain,  fruit-and-nut,  and  livestock  farms, 

Table  35. — Percentage  of  Total  Investment  by  Source  for 
Each  Type  of  Commercial  Farm,  by  Economic  Class,  for 
the  United  States:  1954 


Total 

Economic  class  of  farm 

I 

II 

ni 

rv 

V 

VI 

100 
78 

13 

100 
82 
5 
13 

100 
83 

5 
12 

100 
80 
6 
15 

100 
85 
2 
13 

100 
91 
1 
8 

100 
70 
13 

100 
77 

14 

100 
74 
15 
11 

100 

5 
13 

100 
72 
12 
16 

100 
75 
10 
16 

100 
86 
3 
11 

100 
9 

100 
86 
3 
10 

100 

2 
9 

100 

84 
3 
14 

100 

1 
12 

100 

91 

7 

100 
76 
12 
12 

inn 
77 

14 

100 
76 
17 

7 

100 
87 
3 
10 

100 

11 
12 

100 
80 
9 

11 

100 

2 
10 

100 
78 
9 
13 

100 
83 
5 
12 

100 
85 
3 
12 

100 

5 
16 

100 

15 

100 

90 

100 
71 
12 
17 

100 
76 

14 

100 
75 
14 
11 

inn 

5 
13 

100 
72 
12 
16 

100 

77 

[-1 

100 

3 
10 

100 
76 

10 
14 

100 
80 
5 
14 

100 
82 

13 

100 

80 
6 
15 

100 
83 
2 
15 

inn 
90 
1 
9 

100 

13 
18 

100 

9 
14 

100 
72 
16 
13 

100 
80 

15 

100 
71 
13 
16 

100 
74 
10 

15 

inn 

4 

11 

100 
76 

in 
15 

100 

78 
6 
16 

100 

78 

15 

100 
79 
6 
15 

100 
81 
3 
16 

100 
90 
1 
9 

100 
68 
14 
18 

inn 
77 
8 
1! 

100 
73 
15 
13 

100 
79 
6 
15 

100 
71 

13 
16 

100 

7_< 
11 
17 

100 

5 
13 

100 

75 
10 
15 

100 

5 
17 

100 
75 
9 
16 

100 

78 
7 
15 

100 

3 
16 

100 
90 
1 

100 
68 
14 
18 

100 
79 

14 

100 
73 
M 
13 

100 
80 
5 
15 

inn 
71 
13 
16 

100 
72 
11 
17 

100 
84 
5 
11 

Value  of  land  ami  1. nil. lings 

76 

Cotton. 

100 

Value  of  land  and  buildings 

80 

Value  of  land  and  buildings 

81 

Livestock  other  than  dairy  and  poultry. 

100 

Value  of  livestock 

15 

General,  primarily  livestock 

Value  of  land  and  buildings 

100 
73 

with  about  $50,000  each.  Lowest  investment  is  shown  for  cotton 
and  other  field-crop  and  poultry  farms. 

The  lower  average  investment  for  cotton  and  other  field-crop 
farms  results  from  the  relatively  large  proportion  of  these  types 
that  is  made  up  of  the  smaller  economic  classes  of  farms.  Much 
greater  similarity  exists  between  types  of  farms  in  the  same 
economic  class.  For  example,  Class  I  cotton  farms  with  a  total 
investment  of  nearly  $200,000  per  farm  are  among  the  highest 
in  capital  requirements.  Among  each  type  of  farm,  except  poultry, 
the  total  investment  on  Class  I  farms  was  $100,000  or  more. 

Capital  investment  is  fairly  similar  among  types  of  farms 
if  comparisons  are  made  by  economic  class.  The  notable  depar- 
tures from  this  are  the  lower  capital  requirements  shown  for  poultry 
farms  and,  among  the  smaller  economic  classes,  the  extremely 
low  capital  investment  on  cotton  and  other  field-crop  farms.  It 
is  to  be  remembered  that  data  for  these  two  types  are  influenced 
by  the  inclusion  of  croppers.  In  general,  however,  the  lower 
capital  investment  is  related  to  the  small  acreage  in  these  farms 
and  the  relatively  low  land  values  per  acre. 

The  total  capital  investment  in  commercial  farming,  as  esti- 
mated here,  was  $110  billion,  in  1954.  The  bulk  of  this  (78 
percent)  was  represented  in  the  value  of  land  and  buildings. 
Livestock  and  machinery  comprised  9  percent  and  13  percent, 
respectively,  of  the  total.     (See  table  35.) 

Land  and  buildings  represented  a  slightly  higher  proportion  of 
the  total  investment  on  farms  having  a  major  source  of  income 
from  crops  than  on  farms  of  the  livestock  types. 

For  each  type  of  farm,  land  and  buildings  represented  a  greater 
proportion  of  the  total  investment  on  the  larger  economic  classes. 
Although  total  investment  was  much  less  on  the  smaller  economic 
classes,  more  of  it  was  in  livestock  and  machinery. 

The  distribution  of  total  investment  by  economic  class  and  by 
type  of  farm  is  shown  in  table  36.  Slightly  more  than  a  fifth  of 
the  total  investment  is  on  Class  I  farms.  Although  these  farms 
produced  about  one-third  of  all  farm  products  sold  in  1954,  in 
terms  of  numbers,  they  accounted  for  only  4  percent  of  the  com- 
mercial farms.  On  Class  I  farms,  the  proportion  of  the  total 
investment  for  land  and  buildings  was  larger  than  for  either  live- 
stock or  machinery. 

The  intermediate  economic  classes  (II,  III,  and  IV)  taken 
together  accounted  for  about  two-thirds  of  the  total  investment. 
They  had  approximately  an  equal  value  of  land  and  buildings  and 
livestock  and  more  than  70  percent  of  the  value  of  machinery. 

Economic  Classes  V  and  VI,  which  comprised  a  third  of  the 
farm  numbers,  accounted  for  only  13  percent  of  the  total  invest- 
ment. A  slightly  higher  proportion  of  the  livestock  value  and 
machinery  value,  than  of  land  and  buildings,  was  on  these  forms. 

Two  types  of  farms,  cash-grain  and  livestock,  accounted  for 
more  than  half  of  the  total  investment.  If  the  investment  on 
dairy  farms  is  added,  two-thirds  of  the  total  investment  was  on 
these  three  types.  They  accounted  for  approximately  two-thirds 
of  the  value  of  land  and  buildings  and  machinery  and  four-fifths 
of  the  value  of  livestock.  Other  livestock  farms  alone  made  up 
half  of  the  total  livestock  investment. 


42 


FARMERS  AND  FARM  PRODUCTION 


Table  36. — Percent  Distribution  of  Total  Investment  by 
Economic  Class  and  by  Type  of  Farm,  for  the  United 
States:  1954 


Value  of 

nvestment 

Economic  class  and  type  of  farm 

Total 

Land  and 
buildings 

Livestock 
inventory 

Machinery 
and  equip- 
ment 

All  commercial  farms  (million 

110, 545 

100.  n 
21.0 
27.1 
23.7 
15.7 

3  4 

100.0 
23.3 
8.0 
4.5 
1.3 

4.2 
13.2 

2.5 

31.1 

2.7 
1.6 
6.3 
1.2 

85,  768 

100.0 
22.2 
27.3 
23.1 
15.1 
8.8 
3.3 

100.0 
24.6 
8.5 

L5 

5.0 
11.9 

2.5 

29.6 

2.9 
1.4 
6.1 
1.4 

10, 497 

100.0 
19.2 
25.6 
24.9 
16.9 
9.7 
3.8 

100.0 
11.7 
4.2 
2.7 
0.3 

0.5 
17.9 
2.3 

49.8 

1.3 
2.1 
6.8 
0.4 

Percent    distribution    by    economic 
class : 

Percent  distribution  by  type  of  farm : 

Livestock  other  than  dairy  and 

General: 

Value  of  Farm  Products  Sold 

The  total  value  of  farm  products  sold  from  commercial  farms 
amounted  to  $24.3  billion  in  1954.  The  distribution  of  gross 
sales  of  farm  products  among  types  of  farms  is  more  equitable 
than  that  of  land  resources  or  the  value  of  investment.  For 
example,  cash-grain  farms,  which  contained  more  than  a  third  of 
the  harvested  cropland,  produced  only  a  fifth  of  the  farm  products 
sold.  Livestock  farms,  with  half  the  land  in  farms,  produced  only 
a  fourth  of  the  farm  products  sold.  On  the  other  hand,  dairy, 
cotton,  and  other  field-crop  farms,  and  the  less  numerous  highly 
specialized  farm  types  such  as  vegetable,  fruit-and-nut,  and 
poultry,  accounted  for  substantially  more  of  the  gross  sales  than 
the  amount  or  value  of  farm  resources. 

By  economic  class  of  farm,  however,  a  much  greater  proportion 
of  gross  sales  than  of  farm  resources  is  shown  for  the  larger  eco- 
nomic classes.  Class  I  farms  accounted  for  nearly  three-fourths 
of  the  gross  sales  from  vegetable  farms  and  two-fifths  that  from 
fruit-and-nut  farms.  (See  table  37.)  About  two-fifths  of  the 
gross  sales  from  cotton,  poultry,  livestock,  and  general  crop  farms 
was  from  Class  I  farms.  In  contrast,  more  than  three-fourths  of 
the  gross  sales  from  dairy,  general  livestock,  and  general  crop  and 
livestock  farms,  was  sold  from  the  medium-size  Classes  II,  III, 
and  IV. 

The  average  value  of  farm  products  sold  per  commercial  farm 
is  shown  in  table  38.  The  average  commercial  farm  grossed 
slightly  more  than  $7,000  in  1954.  This  average  ranged  from 
about  $4,000  on  other  field-crop  farms  to  $16,000  on  vegetable 
farms. 


Table  37. — Percent  Distribution  of  Gross  Sales  for  Each 
Type  of  Farm  by  Economic  Class,  for  the  United  States: 
1954 


Type  of  farm 

Total 

Economic  class  of  farm 

I 

n 

III 

IV 

V 

VI 

100.0 
100.0 
100.0 
100.0 
100.0 

100.0 
100.0 
100.0 

100.0 

100.0 
100.0 
100.  0 
100.0 

22.3 
40.8 
20.8 
72.6 

59  3 
16.4 
43.7 

37.8 

42.0 
6.8 
12.3 
65.1 

27.5 
36.4 
15.1 
14.4 
13.2 

20.8 
30.1 
30.2 

30.2 

22.8 
29.7 
31.7 
18.0 

20.9 
26.1 
12.2 
20.7 
6.9 

10.8 
31.0 
14.2 

18.1 

16.1 
34.1 
31.8 
7.7 

12.4 
11.1 
15.2 
26.6 
4.3 

5.9 
16.1 
7.0 

8.7 

11.7 
20.2 

17.1 
5.2 

5.8 
3.5 
12.7 
141 
2.2 

5.4 
3.7 

4.1 

6.1 
7.6 
6.1 
3.1 

Livestock    other    than    dairy    and 

General: 

Table  38. — Average  Value  of  Farm  Products  Sold  per 
Farm  by  Type  and  Economic  Class,  for  the  United  States: 
1954 


Total 

Economic  class  of  farm 

I 

II 

III 

IV 

V 

VI 

Value  of  farm  products  sold  per 
All  commercial  farms 

Dol- 
lars 

7.:i(i_> 
s,  ::ii'. 
1.962 

iiijir,:: 

14,409 

6,  529 
9,634 

8,828 

7,365 

5,  436 

6,  244 
13,  189 

Dollars 
57,997 

i,-i.  ;.v2 

69,744 
59,  586 
101,301 

65,  099 
511,130 
49,400 

58, 114 

65,432 

39. 1',f.'.l 
47,  502 
70,  963 

Dol- 
lars 

14.883 
14.77C. 
15.  13) 
14.939 
15,458 

10,083 
14,178 
15,727 

15,246 
13,478 

14.26N 
14.129 
15,117 

Dol- 
lars 
7,178 
7,315 

6,  787 
6,917 
7,037 

7,806 

7. 1199 

7,359 
7,296 

6,579 
7,145 
7,165 
6,845 

Dol- 

3,703 
3.  846 
3,418 
3,716 
3,492 

4,108 
3,  744 
3,808 

3,745 

3,411 

3,714 
3,  689 
3,  536 

Dol- 

1,851 
1,911 
1,765 
1,924 
1,737 

2,041 

1,886, 

1,878 
1,834 

1,708 

1,886 
1,877 
1,830 

Dol- 
756 

Cotton 

Other  field-crop. 

769 
806 

Fruit-and-nut 

798 

Livestock  oilier  than  dairy 

General: 

Primardy  livestock 

Crop  and  livestock 

812 

825 

The  averages  by  economic  class  show  the  extreme  range  in  size 
of  business  that  characterizes  farming  in  the  United  States. 
Class  I  farms  are  50  to  100  times  as  large  in  business  volume  as 
Class  VI  farms.  The  two  extremes  would  compare  Class  I  vege- 
table farms  with  gross  sales  of  more  than  $100,000  and  Class  VI 
vegetable  farms  with  gross  sales  of  less  than  $700. 

Since  the  economic  classification  (based  on  the  value  of  farm 
sales)  groups  farms  within  fairly  narrow  intervals  of  value,  a  close 
similarity  is  found  in  the  average  sales  for  each  type  by  economic 
class.  The  exception  is  for  Class  I  farms  which  contain  all  farms 
with  gross  sales  of  $25,000  or  more.  The  effect  of  the  open-end 
value  grouping  is  apparent  in  the  averages  for  Class  I  which  range 
from  less  than  $40,000  to  more  than  $100,000. 


A  GENERAL  VIEW 


43 


Gross  Sales  Per  Acre 

The  value  of  farm  products  sold  per  acre  of  total  land  in  farms 
is  shown  for  types  and  economic  classes  of  farms  in  table  39.  For 
commercial  farms  as  a  group,  the  sales  per  acre  averaged  $24  in 
1954.  The  average  for  all  commercial  farms  is  weighted  heavily 
by  cash-grain  and  other  livestock  farms.  Many  of  these  farms 
are  located  in  semiarid  western  regions  where  production  per  acre 
is  relatively  low.  The  average  sale  per  acre  was  $12  for  livestock 
farms  and  $22  for  cash-grain  farms  in  1954. 

Gross  sales  per  acre  were  highest  on  vegetable,  fruit-and-nut, 
and  poultry  farms,  averaging  more  than  $100  per  acre.  All  other 
types  ranged  between  $25  and  $50  per  acre. 

Gross  sales  per  acre  decreased  with  decreasing  size  of  farm. 
For  commercial  farms  as  a  group,  Class  I  farms  had  sales  per  acre 
about  4  times  greater  than  Class  VI  farms.  For  some  types  of 
farms,  however,  the  differential  between  the  larger  and  smaller 
economic  classes  was  much  greater. 


Table  39. — Value  of  All  Farm  Products  Sold  per  Acre  of 
Total  Land  in  Farms,  by  Type  of  Commercial  Farm  by 
Economic  Class  of  Farm,  for  the  United  States:  1954 


Total 

Economic  class  of 

arm 

I 

II 

III 

IV 

V 

VI 

All  commercial  farms 

Dot- 

24 
22 
40 

47 
110 

121 
37 

12 

27 
30 
24 
47 

Dol. 

30 
31 

68 
89 
159 

145 
99 
303 

51 

40 
119 

Dol- 
lars 
28 
26 

63 
111 

133 
53 
166 

15 

30 
57 
36 
39 

Dol- 
lars 
23 

20 
35 
56 
72 

108 
37 
92 

13 

22 
36 

25 

Dol- 
lars 
18 
15 
34 
47 
45 

76 
25 
55 

9 

18 
Iti 

Dol- 
lars 
14 

28 
29 
26 

47 
15 

12 
13 
12 

Dol- 
lars 
8 

Livestock  other  than  dairy  and 

General: 

Yield  of  Corn  Per  Acre  Harvested 

Yields  of  corn  per  acre  by  type  and  economic  class  of  farm 
substantiate  the  differentials  in  gross  productivity  shown  pre- 
viously. Corn  is  the  most  widely  grown  crop  in  the  United 
States.  Its  acreage  surpasses  that  of  any  other  crop.  It  is  a 
relatively  important  crop  on  most  types  and  economic  classes  of 
farms.  Most  farmers  do  not  sell  corn,  except  for  incidental 
sales;  they  grow  it  for  feed.  Thus,  for  most  types  of  farms,  corn 
has  relatively  small  influence  in  determining  either  the  type  or 
the  economic  class.  Exceptions,  of  course,  are  the  cash-grain  and 
general  farms  on  which  corn  is  an  important  cash  crop.  The 
yield  of  corn  in  a  particular  year  influences  the  number  of  livestock 
purchased,  fed,  and  sold  on  livestock  farms. 

The  yield  of  corn  per  acre  harvested  is  shown  for  each  type  of 
farm,  by  economic  class,  in  table  40.  The  average  yield  for  all 
commercial  farms  was  40  bushels  per  acre  in  1954.  As  would  be 
expected,  yields  were  higher  than  average  on  types  of  farms  on 
which  corn  for  feed  or  for  sale  was  an  important  enterprise — cash- 
grain,  dairy,  other  livestock,  general  livestock,  and  general  crop 
and  livestock  farms.  Yields  were  lowest  on  cotton,  other  field- 
crop,  and  general  crop  farms. 

On  each  type  of  farm,  however,  yields  of  corn  were  highest  on 
Economic    Class   I   farms   and    decreased   for   each   successively 


smaller  economic  class.     Yields  on  Class  VI  farms  were  approxi- 
mately half  those  realized  on  Class  I  farms. 

Table  40. — Yield  per  Acre  of  Corn  Harvested  for  Grain, 
by  Type  of  Commercial  Farm  and  by  Economic  Class  of 
Farm,  for  the  United  States:  1954 


Type  of  Farm 

Total 

Economic  class  of  farm 

1 

II 

III 

IV 

V 

VI 

All  commercial 

Bushels 
40 

14 
23 
34 

36 

48 
38 

45 

47 
41 
23 

Bushels 
64 
58 
23 
41 
47 

42 

55 
49 

57 

42 
63 
54 
25 

Bushels 
50 

17 
31 
41 

55 
40 

35 

52 
30 

Bushels 
41 
42 

25 
35 

35 
50 

28 
60 
41 
21 

Bushels 
31 
36 
14 
22 
30 

34 

43 
33 

34 

22 
39 
31 
21 

I'.usheh 
24 
32 
12 
21 
23 

20 
33 
31 

28 

20 
33 

20 

Bushels 

other  field-crop 

20 

Livestock     other     than 
dairy  and  poultry 

General: 
Primarily  crop 

Primarily  livestock.... 

Crop  and  livestock 

Miscellaneous 

22 

17 
26 
21 
17 

Gross  Sales  Per  $100  of  Capital  Investment 

For  commercial  agriculture  as  a  whole,  gross  sales  averaged 
$22  in  1954  for  each  $100  of  capital  invested  in  land,  buildings, 
livestock,  and  machinery  (see  table  41).  At  this  rate  it  takes 
approximately  4  years  of  gross  farm  sales  to  equal  in  value  the 
capital  invested  in  agriculture. 

Table  41. — Value  of  All  Farm  Products  Sold  per  $100  of 
Capital  Invested  in  Land  and  Buildings,  Livestock,  and 
Machinery,  by  Type  of  Commercial  Farm  by  Economic 
Class  of  Farm,  for  the  United  States:  1954 


Type  of  farm 

Total 

Economic  class  of  farm 

1 

11 

III 

IV 

V 

VI 

All  commercial  farms 

Dollars 
22 
17 
31 
33 
30 

28 
25 
54 

18 

21 
20 
18 
40 

Dollars 
35 
24 
36 
45 
46 

37 
40 
112 

30 

30 
36 
29 

72 

Dollars 
23 
18 
26 
33 
29 

26 
28 
66 

19 

20 
26 
21 
32 

Hull,  II.-. 

19 
16 

27 
34 
23 

21 
24 

43 

18 
21 
18 
23 

Dollars 
17 
13 
31 
33 
17 

16 

27 

11 

17 
16 
15 

17 

Dollars 
14 
10 
29 
26 

10 

8 

11 
12 
12 

Dollars 

Livestock  othei  than  dairy  and 

General: 

Crop  and  livestock 

Sales  per  unit  of  investment  were  highest  on  poultry  farms.  In 
general,  sales  per  unit  of  investment  were  higher  on  farms  having 
a  major  source  of  income  from  crops  than  from  livestock  types. 
Cash-grain  farms  were  the  only  notable  exception  to  this;  they 
averaged  only  $17  per  unit  of  investment. 

Sales  per  unit  of  investment  decrease  with  decreasing  size. 
The  differentials  are  large  for  some  types.  Class  I  poultry  farms, 
for  example,  had  sales  per  unit  of  investment  nearly  15  times 
greater  than  Class  VI  farms  of  this  type.  In  contrast,  the  dif- 
ferentials between  economic  classes  of  cotton  farms  were  relatively 
small. 


44 


FARMERS  AND  FARM  PRODUCTION 


Gross  Sales  per  Man-Equivalent 

Gross  farm  sales  per  man-equivalent  amounted  to  $5,000  for 
all  commercial  farms  in  1954  (see  table  42).  These  ranged  from 
a  high  of  more  than  $8,000  for  poultry  farms  to  a  low  of  about 
$3,000  on  cotton  and  other  field-crop  farms.  Cash-grain  and 
livestock  farms,  which  had  the  lowest  sales  per  acre,  were  among 
the  highest  types  in  sales  per  man-equivalent. 


Table  42. — Value  of  All  Farm  Products  Sold  per  Man-Equiv 
alent  of  Labor  Used,  by  Type  of  Commercial  Farm  by 
Economic  Class  of  Farm,  for  the  United  States:  1954 


Total 

Economic  class  of  farm 

I 

II 

III 

IV 

V 

VI 

All  commercial  farms 

Dulhir.; 

r,(un 
(',.  785 
2,919 
2,  877 
4,497 

5,857 

1,  ."A! 
8,305 

6,791 

4,575 
4,214 
4.  558 
4,831 

Dollars 

III,  TIM 
14,848 

S,  '.CSS 

c,  '.137 
5,685 

7,292 

'J,  353 
18,  229 

17,  772 

8,251 

III,  tr,l 
111.97(1 
5,774 

D„ll„,t, 
s,  223 

i-.!  147 
C,  173 
4,306 

6,115 

7.197 
10,  998 

9,470 

6,511 

8,  -143 
8.  1211 
5,399 

Dollars 
5,  0211 
5,947 
3,517 

3,  864 
3,518 

4,848 

4,  8(12 
6,512 

5,486 

4,300 

5,032 

5,  (140 
4,123 

Dollars 

2,  010 

3.  840 
2,035 
2,477 
2,442 

3,668 

2,  005 
4,051 

3,344 

2,729 

2,  0 18 
2,  028 

3,048 

Dollars 
1,008 
2,3112 
1,261 
1,50(1 
1,608 

2,373 

1,700 
2,439 

2,084 

1,708 

1,700 
1,754 
2,128 

Dollars 
727 

Livestock  other  than  daily  und 

General: 

Sales  per  man-equivalent  were  highest  on  Class  I  farms  for 
each  type.  They  decreased  substantially  for  each  successively 
smaller  economic  class.  For  each  type  of  farm  the  differential 
between  economic  classes  is  fairly  similar.  Each  successively 
smaller  economic  class  had  gross  sales  per  man-equivalent  only 
half  to  two-thirds  that  of  the  economic  class  above  it.  Gross 
sales  per  man-equivalent  for  Class  I  farms  was  10  to  20  times 
greater  than  for  Class  VI  farms. 

Limitations  of  Relating  Sales  to  Resources 

Comparisons  of  gross  productivity  per  unit  of  farm  resources 
do  not  take  account  of  farm  expenses.  The  proportion  of  farm 
sales  that  is  net  varies  by  type  of  farm  as  well  as  between  economic 
classes  within  each  type.  The  effect  of  these  variations  is  prob- 
ably more  important  between  types  of  farm,  however,  than  be- 
tween classes  of  the  same  type.  Farm  expenses  and  the  propor- 
tion they  comprise  of  gross  farm  sales  are  discussed  later  in  this 
report. 

In  addition,  sales  per  unit  of  resources  between  economic 
classes  of  farms  are  affected  by  classification  on  the  basis  of  sales 
in  the  particular  year.  They  may  have  been  higher  or  lower 
than  normal  because  of  chance  factors. 

In  view  of  the  wide  differentials  between  economic  classes  of 
farms  shown  in  the  preceding  tables,  it  is  reasonable  to  conclude 
that  resources  are  used  to  greater  efficiency  on  the  larger  economic 
classes.  The  precise  amount  of  these  differentials,  however, 
cannot  be  determined  from  the  existing  data. 


Investment  per  Man-Equivalent 

Differences  in  gross  productivity  per  worker  between  types  and 
economic  classes  of  farms  may  be  partly  attributable  to  differences 
in  the  amount  of  other  resources  at  the  disposal  of  workers  on 
these  farms.  The  capital  investment  discussed  previously, 
provides  an  indication  of  the  total  nonlabor  resources.  The 
capital  investment  per  farm  was  divided  by  the  man-equivalents 
per  farm  to  provide  the  data  shown  in  table  43. 

The  investment  per  man-equivalent  worker  for  commercial 
agriculture  as  a  whole  was  about  $22,000  in  1954.  For  cash-grain 
and  livestock  farms  the  average  was  nearly  $40,000.  The  lowest 
average  investment  per  worker  was  on  cotton  and  other  field-crop 
farms,  an  average  of  less  than  $10,000. 

By  economic  class  of  farm,  the  highest  investment  per  worker 
was  on  Classes  I  and  II.  This  was  true  for  all  types  except 
vegetable  farms.  For  vegetable  farms  the  investment  per  worker 
was  highest  in  Class  III. 

Investment  per  worker  decreased  with  decreasing  size  of  farm; 
the  lowest  investment  was  found  on  Class  VI  farms.  The 
exception  is  that  investment  per  worker  was  higher  on  Class  II 
than  on  Class  I  for  all  types  except  cash-grain  and  cotton  farms. 

Class  II  farms  are  mostly  family  operated.  That  is,  the  farm 
operator  and  members  of  his  family  comprise  most  of  the  labor 
force.  These  farms  as  a  group  typify  the  large,  up-to-date, 
highly  mechanized  family  farms.  Many  Class  I  farms  also  are 
operated  primarily  with  family  labor,  but  included  in  this  group 
are  larger  farms  that  hire  most  of  the  farm  work  done. 

Apparently  Class  II  farms  have  reached  sufficient  size  to 
achieve  reasonably  efficient  use  of  most  modern  innovations 
designed  to  increase  output  and  decrease  labor  needs.  The 
income  and  credit  positions  of  families  on  Class  II  farms  have 
probably  been  sufficient  to  enable  them  to  make  profitable  invest- 
ments in  productive  land,  modern  buildings,  and  other  capital 
items.  Workers  on  these  farms  have  capital  resources  to  work 
with  that  are  equal  to  or  greater  than  that  of  workers  on  Class  I 
farms. 

Table  43. — Capital  Investment  in  Land  and  Buildings, 
Livestock  and  Machinery  per  Man-Equivalent  of  Labor 
Used,  by  Type  of  Commercial  Farm  by  Economic  Class  of 
Farm,  for  the  United  States:  1954 


Total 

Economic  olass  of  farm 

I 

II 

III 

IV 

V 

VI 

All    commercial 

Dollars 
22,516 

"\l.  301 
8,736 
12,  665 

20,  972 

is.  377 
15,  461 

22,281 

21,401 
21.013 

12,154 

Dollars 

30,  113 
01,000 
25.  127 
15.415 
12,  318 

19,  921 

23,  1 13 
16,  316 

68,  665 
27,  689 

20.  300 
37,812 

8,069 

Dollars 

30,431 
53,  054 
23,  300 
1.8,  450 
14,960 

23,449 

25,  504 
16,646 

48,857 

32,  813 

32,318 
37,841 
16,  919 

Dollars 

37,'  4  11 
13,  18S 
11,350 
15,  574 

23,  265 

10,  002 
15, 187 

36, 115 

23,651 

24,  443 
27,  872 
18,260 

Dollars 

10,704 
28,541 
6,588 
7,419 
14,  243 

23,  010 

15.200 

14,978 
29,  406 

16,  411 

17,050 
10.880 

18,  078 

Dollars 

12,000 

22.  1-10 
4,390 
6,114 

13,087 

23,  574 

12,570 
15,388 

25,605 
15,350 

15,221 
14,838 
19,  008 

Dollars 

4,489 

Fruit-and-nut 

13,  221 

8,670 

Livestock     other    than 
dairy  and  poultry 

General: 
Primarily  crop 

Primarily  livestock,.  . 
Crop  and  livestock 

14,061 

10,  553 

11,300 
9,77(1 
10,720 

A  GENERAL  VIEW 


45 


TOTAL  FARM  EXPENSES 

Data  on  total  farm  expenses  are  available  from  a  farm  expendi- 
ture survey  taken  in  the  spring  of  1956  by  the  Bureau  of  the 
Census  and  the  Agricultural  Marketing  Service  which  has  pro- 
vided needed  information  on  the  production  expenses  of  farmers. 
In  this  survey  a  sample  of  approximately  6,600  farmers  answered 
detailed  questions  covering  their  farm  expenses  for  the  calendar 
year  1955.  For  an  explanation  of  the  sample  design  and  pro- 
cedure and  for  an  estimate  of  the  sampling  error,  see  volume  III, 
part  11. 

One  tabulation  obtained  from  the  survey  was  by  type  of  farm 
and  by  selected  economic  classes  of  farms.  The  average  per  farm 
of  the  major  categories  of  farm  expenses  by  type  of  farm  arc 
shown  in  table  44.  These  farm  expenses  relate  to  1955.  Other 
data  on  farm  and  farm-operator  characteristics  contained  in  this 
report  are  from  the  1954  Census  of  Agriculture  and  relate  to  1954. 


For  this  reason  direct  comparison  of  the  two  sets  of  data  would 
not  be  meaningful.  Also,  the  farm  expenses  obtained  in  the 
survey  included  expenses  incurred  for  family  living  that  ordinarily 
would  not  be  charged  against  the  farm  business.  (See  footnotes 
to  table  44.)  In  addition,  the  production  expenses  for  cropper 
farms  obtained  in  the  survey  were  included  in  the  economic  class 
in  which  the  landlord's  home  farm  was  tabulated. 

Data  from  the  survey  are  useful  primarily  in  showing  the  relative 
magnitude  of  categories  of  farm  expenses  for  different  types  and 
sizes  of  farms  and  the  proportions  these  categories  comprise  of 
total  farm  expenses.  These  relationships  may  also  be  useful  in 
examination  of  the  specified  expense  items  obtained  by  the  1954 
Census  of  Agriculture.  An  attempt  is  made  later  in  this  report  to 
indicate  the  extent  to  which  the  Census  specified  expense  items  are 
representative  of  total  farm  expenses  for  the  different  types  and 
economic  classes  of  farms. 


Table  44. — Cash  Farm  Expenditures:  Average  per  Farm  by  Type  of  Farm  by  Economic  Class,  for  the  United  States:  1955 


Expenditure  by  economic  class  of  farm 


ALL  CLASSES 


Total  expenditures 

Cash  wages 

Machine  hire  and  cnstomwork 

Livestock  and  poultry  purchased. 
Feed  for  livestock  and  poultry 


Dollars 
12,. '171 
4,414 


Seeds,  plants,  and  trees 

Commercial  fertilizer  and  liming  materials 

Petroleum  product--,  farm  business  share  i. 

Repair  and  other  operating  costs  for  motor  vehicles  and  farm  ma- 
chinery'  

Marketing  costs - 


Miscellaneous  current  operating  oxpen-e,  not  included  elsewhere  ' 

Property  taxes,  farm  business  share  * 

Interest,  farm  business  share  » 

Constiuotion  mid  land  improvement' 

Purchase  of  motor  vehicles,  farm  machinery  and  equipment 7._  .. 

CLASSES  I  AND  II 


Total  expenditures— 

("ash  iiaees 

Machine  lure  mid  cnstomwork.-  - 
Livestock  and  poultry  purchased 
Feed  for  livestock  and  poultry 


Seeds,  plant",  and  trees-_ 

Commercial  fertilize]  and  limine  materials 

Petroleum  products,  farm  business  share  ' 

Kepair  and  oilier  operating  costs  for  motor  vehicles  and  farm  ; 

chinery  3 _. 

Marketing  costs - 


Miscellaneous  current  upending  expense,  not  included  elsewhere  ' 

Property  taxi's,  farm  business  share  * 

Interest,  farm  business  share  > 

Construction  mid  land  improvement' 

Purchase  of  motor  vehicles,  farm  machinery  and  equipment T 


1,957 
2,046 


CLASSICS  HI  THROUGH  VI 


Total  expenditures , 

Cash  wages 

Machine  lure  and  cnstomwork 

Livestock  and  poultry  purchased. 
Feed  for  livestock  and  poultry 


Seeds,  plants,  and  trees- 

Commercial  fertilizer  and  limine  materials 

Petroleum  products,  farm  business  share  ' 

Repair  and  other  operating  costs  for  mob 

chinery  ' 

Marketing  costs 


vehicles  and  farm 


Miscellaneous  current  op.aatiug  expense,  not  included  elsewhere  ' 

Property  taxes,  farm  business  share  * 

Interest,  farm  business  share  > _.. 

Construction  mid  land  improvement'- _ _ 

Purchase  of  motor  vehicles,  farm  machinery  and  equipment 7 


1  Expenditures  minus  tax  refunds.     Includes  expenditures  attributable  to  uses  other  I  ban  farm  business. 

'  Includes  repairs,  icplaccmcnl  parts,  accessories,  registration  far.  and  insurani n  vehicles.     Includes  expenditures  attributable  to  uses  oilier  than  farm  lni,.moss. 

»  Medicine,  disinti  etaiils,  pesticides,  electricity,  telephone  service,  insurance,  hand  loots,  and  miscellaneous  farm  business  expenses   (management  sei  vices,  recordkeeping,  legal 
fees,  advertising  expenses,  etc.). 

1  Includes  some  properly  laves  on  furniture  and  other  household  goods  attributable  to  family  li 


*  Includes  interest  on  debt  contiacted  lor  family  living  expenses. 

'■  Kxrludes  expend)  tines  by  landlords,  excludes  expenditures  for  construction  and  repair  of 

'  Purchase  cost  minus  value  of  trade-in  and  sales.    Includes  expenditures  atti  Unliable  to  uses  other  than  farm  business. 


oiling  except,  for  multi-unit  t 


46 


FARMERS  AND  FARM  PRODUCTION 


Cash  wages. — The  expenditure  for  hired  labor  amounted  to 
$764  for  the  average  commercial  farm  in  1955  and  comprised 
about  a  tenth  of  the  total  farm  expenses.  Cash  wages  were  a 
much  more  important  expense  on  some  types  of  farms  than  others. 
In  general,  cash-grain  farms  and  types  of  farms  having  a  major 
source  of  income  from  livestock  products  had  relatively  small 
expense  for  hired  labor,  amounting  to  7  percent  or  less  of  the  total 
expenses.  (See  table  45.)  On  farms  with  a  major  source  of 
income  from  crops  (except  cash-grain  farms)  cash  wages  ranged 
from  nearly  a  fifth  to  a  fourth  or  more  of  the  total  farm  expenses. 


The  farm  expenses  have  been  tabulated  into  two  economic 
class  groups — Classes  I  and  II,  which  combine  all  farms  with  sales 
of  farm  products  valued  at  $10,000  or  more,  and  Classes  III,  IV, 
V,  and  VI,  a  combination  of  commercial  farms  that  had  sales  of 
farm  products  valued  at  less  than  $10,000. 

Cash  wages  comprised  a  higher  proportion  of  total  expenses 
on  the  larger  economic  classes  of  farms  than  on  the  smaller 
classes — 14  percent  and  7  percent,  respectively,  for  all  types  taken 
together.  A  similar  relationship  existed  between  the  two  size 
groups  for  each  type  individually. 


Table  45. — Cash  Farm  Expenditures  as  a  Percentage  of  Total  Farm  Expenditures, 

Farm,  for  the  United  States:  1955 


Type  of  Farm,  by  Economic  Class  of 


All 

cial 
farms 

Type  of  farm 

Cash- 
grain 

Cotton 

Other 
field- 
crop 

table 

Fruit- 
and- 

Dairy 

Poul- 
try 

Live- 
stock 
other 

poultry 

General— 

Pri- 
marily 
crop 

Pri- 

m.'U'ilv 
live- 
stock 

live- 
stock 

Mis- 
cella- 

ALL  CLASSES 

Percent 
100.0 
10.8 
2.3 
10.8 
17.2 

3.4 

5.4 
8.5 

6.1 
4.7 

6.9 
3.2 
2.3 
5.3 
13.1 

100.0 
14.2 
1.7 
13.7 
18.2 

3.1 

5.2 

5.2 
5.2 

7.2 
2.7 
2.0 

10^5 

100.0 
6.9 
3.1 
7.5 
16.2 

3.8 
5.6 
11.1 

7.2 
4.1 

6.5 
3.8 
2.6 
5.6 
15.9 

Percent 
100.0 

3^1 
8.2 
7.2 

4.6 
6.8 
12.3 

9.5 
2.8 

6.6 
4.1 
2.5 
5.2 
20.4 

100.0 
9.1 
2.6 

6^7 

4.6 
7.9 
10.8 

9.4 
3.0 

3^5 
2.1 
5.7 
18.9 

100.0 
4.8 
3.6 
8.0 
7.6 

4.5 

2^5 

6.2 
4.6 
3.0 
4.8 
21.7 

Percent 
100.0 
23.4 
2.9 
3.6 
3.1 

3.5 

7.0 
9.6 

7.0 
8.2 

7.6 
1.5 
2.4 
4.7 
15.7 

100.0 

27.4 
2.8 
3.2 
1.8 

3.4 
6.9 
7.9 

6.6 
8.8 

9.8 
1.5 
2.3 
5.1 
12.4 

100.0 
18.2 
3.0 
4.0 
4.7 

3.5 
7.3 
11.8 

7.4 
7.3 

4.8 

2^5 
4.4 
19.8 

Percent 
100.0 
19.4 
2.8 
3.0 
4.3 

5.5 
11.2 

9.9 

6.7 
5.8 

7.8 
2.3 
2.2 
6.1 
13.1 

1110.  0 
29.3 
2.2 
3.0 
2.3 

6.2 
10.0 
5.7 

5.3 
6.7 

10.4 
2.5 
2.0 

8^0 

100.0 
10.5 
3.3 

6.1 

4.9 
12.2 
13.7 

7.9 
4.9 

5.4 
2.2 
2.3 
5.9 
17.7 

11.0    0 

27.5 
1.1 
1.0 
1.4 

6.3 
9.8 
5.9 

4.9 
17.8 

8.6 
3.0 
1.5 
5.7 
5.6 

100.0 

30.7 
1.0 
0.7 
1.0 

4.7 
11.1 
4.2 

4.2 
21.3 

8.3 
2.2 
1.4 
4.3 
5.1 

100.0 

L4 
1.6 
2.3 

9.9 
7.2 

6.4 
10.0 

9.4 

1.5 

8.8 
6.6 

1011    II 

29.5 
1.2 
1.3 
2.5 

1.9 
6.8 
5.7 

4.5 
14.8 

11.4 
3.6 
1.6 
4.8 

10.5 

100.0 
32.2 

lie 

2.0 

1.3 

6.6 
4.7 

4.2 
17.4 

11.8 
3.4 
1.4 
4.7 

8.1 

100.0 
23.2 
1.9 
0.6 
3.9 

3.6 
7.4 
8.1 

5.3 

8.8 

10.4 
3.9 
2.0 
5.0 

15.9 

mil  i'i 

7.3 
2.5 
5.3 
25.1 

2.8 
4.2 
8.4 

6.8 
4.9 

7.4 
3.7 
2.6 
5.6 
14.5 

100.0 
11.8 
1.4 
5.  6 
30.8 

2.3 
4.1 

4.4 

4.7 

7.3 
2.7 
2.2 
5.2 
12.1 

100.0 
4.5 
3.1 
5.1 
21.5 

3.1 

10^2 

6.6 
5.0 

4.4 
2.8 
5.8 
16.0 

Percent 
100.0 
4.0 
0.6 
12.8 
68.2 

0.7 
1.2 
3.8 

L8 

4.0 
1.4 
1.3 
3.9 
4.5 

100.0 
5.0 

12!  5 

61.3 

0.5 
0.8 
2.6 

1.4 
1.7 

3.9 
1.1 
1.3 

3.6 

4.0 

100.0 
1.9 

13!  3 

61.9 

1.2 
2.0 
6.2 

3.4 
1.9 

4.2 
1.9 
1.3 
4.5 
5.3 

Percent 
100.0 

2.0 
22.0 

20.0 

2.6 
3.9 
7.1 

5.3 
2.7 

6.2 
3.6 
2.5 
5.3 
10.3 

100.0 
7.7 
1.3 
29.1 
20.4 

2.1 
3.3 
5.2 

4.4 

2.5 

5.9 
3.1 
2.3 
4.3 
8.4 

100.0 
4.7 
3.0 
12.0 
19.5 

3.4 

9i  9 

6.6 
3.0 

6.6 
4.3 
2.6 
6.6 
13.0 

l'l'irt'nt 
100.0 
17.6 
3.7 
4.6 
3.8 

5.1 
9.2 
9.8 

6.4 
6.1 

9.3 
2.5 
1.9 
5.8 
14.4 

100.0 
21.2 
3.3 

5.2 
2.4 

4.6 

8.8 
7.8 

6.1 
8.3 

10.6 
2.1 
1.5 
5.8 

12.4 

100.0 
11.7 
4.3 
3.5 
6.1 

5.8 
9.6 
13.2 

6.8 
2.5 

7.1 
3.3 

2.5 
5.7 
17.9 

toil  0 
4.4 
3.0 
7.1 
23.7 

3.4 

9^9 

6.3 
3.7 

6.8 
3.8 
2.2 
5.7 
15.4 

100.0 
8.3 
1.7 
6.9 
25.1 

2.9 
6.2 

7.1 

5.6 
3.5 

6.9 
3.0 
1.2 
6.4 
15.1 

100.0 
2.9 
3.5 
7.2 
23.1 

3.6 

10^9 

6.6 
3.8 

6.8 
4.2 
2.6 

5.  4 
15.5 

Pliant 
100.0 
7.1 
3.3 
9.2 
13.8 

4.3 
6.7 
10.6 

7.5 
4.2 

7.0 
3.5 
2.4 
6.4 
13.9 

100.0 
10.4 

2.4 
13.1 
13.5 

3.5 
7.3 
7.6 

6.2 
4.5 

6.9 
2.8 
2.6 
6.7 
12.6 

100.0 

i.O 
6.6 
14.1 

4.8 
6.4 
12.7 

8.5 
3.9 

4^0 
2.3 
6.3 
14.8 

Pinrnt 

Repair  and  other  oporathii;  costs  fur  motor  vehicles  and  farm  ma- 

Miscellaneous  current  operating  expense,  not  included  elsewhere3.. . 

8.0 

Purchase  of  motor  vehicles,  faun  machinery  and  equipment  ;...__ 
CLASSES  I  AND  II 

7.5 

Livestock  and  poultry  putcha-ed   

0.8 

15.0 

Commercial  fertilizer  and  1 1 1 1 1 1 n ur  materials 

3.8 
4.9 

Repair  and  other  operating  costs  for  motor  vehicles  and  farm  ma- 

1.9 

Miscellaneous  current  operator.'  expense,  not  included  elsewhere  3._ 

8.2 
2.1 

1.2 

6.4 

Purchase  of  motor  vehicles,  farm  machinery  and.  equipment7 

CLASSES  III  THROUGH  VI 

4.8 
100.0 

16.6 

1.7 

1.1 

7.2 

Seeds,  plants,  and  frees. 

11.4 
5.1 

10.8 

Repair  and  other  operating  co-is  for  motor  vehicles  and  farm  ma- 

6.5 

6.3 

Miscellaneous  current  operating  expense,  not  included  elsewhere.. 

7.3 
3.7 

Purchase  of  motor  vehicles,  farm  machinery  and  equipment ' 

15.9 

repair; 

3  Medicine,  disinfectants,  pesticides,  electricity,  telephone  sol  \  ice,  insurance,  hand  tools,  and  miscellaneous  faun  business  expenses   (management 
fees,  advertising  expenses,  etc.). 

<  Includes  some  pinj  iert>  taxes  on  fin  nil  u ml  oilier  household  roods  at  nil  m  table  to  family  living  expenses. 

*  Includes  interest  on  debt  contracted  for  family  lix  Hit'  expenses. 

•  Excludes  expenditures  by  landlords,  excludes  expend  nines  en  ■const  met  ion  and  repair  of  opei  at  01's  duel  line  except  for  mulli  mill  tenant  farms. 
»  Purchase  cost  minus  value  of  trade-in  and  sales.     Includes  expenditures  at  tributable  to  use:-  other  than  farm  business. 


A  GENERAL  VIEW 


-17 


Of  the  tot  ill  rush  wages  ]i:ud  m  r01111iMTn.1l  agnciill  ill  f  ■,  cotton 
farms  accounted  for  slightly  more  than  ;i  fifth — a  larger  proportion 
than  any  other  type  (see  table  46).  The  next  highest  users  of 
hired  labor  were  livestock  farms  other  than  dairy  and  poultry 
which  accounted  for  slightly  less  than  a  fifth  of  the  cash  wages 
paid. 

Machine  hire. — The  expenditure  for  machine  hire  was  relatively 
small  for  each  type  and  size  of  farm.  It  amounted  to  $165  for 
commercial  farms  as  a  group  and  accounted  for  only  2  percent  of 
the  total  expenses.  By  type  of  farm  there  was  small  variation. 
For  each  type  of  farm,  however,  machine  hire  was  a  higher  pro- 
portion of  total  expenses  on  the  smaller  economic  classes  of  farms. 
Operators  of  the  smaller  farms  frequently  have  insufficient  acreage 
to  utilize  certain  items  of  farm  machinery  efficiently.  This  indi- 
cates a  tendency  on  the  part  of  many  to  hire  machine  work  done 
on  a  custom  basis. 

Purchase  of  livestock  and  poultry. — About  three-fifths  of  the 
total  expenditures  for  livestock  and  poultry  purchases  by  com- 
mercial farmers  in  1955  was  accounted  for  by  livestock  farms 
other  than  dairy  and  poultry — an  average  of  nearly  $2,000  per 
farm.  On  farms  of  this  type  the  purchase  of  livestock  and 
poultry  was  the  largest  single  expense  item  and  it  amounted  to 
more  than  a  fifth  of  the  total  farm  expenses.  On  other  types  of 
farms  the  proportion  of  this  expense  to  total  expenses  ranged 
from  13  percent  for  poultry  farms  to  only  1  percent  for  vegetable 
and   fruit-and-nut   farms. 


Among  types  of  farms  having  a  major  source  of  income  from 
crops,  the  expense  for  purchase  of  livestock  and  poultry  was  largest 
on  cash-grain  farms.  This  is  an  indication  of  the  importance  of 
livestock  feeding  as  a  secondary  farm  enterprise  for  farmers  who 
raise  and  sell  grains,  especially  feed  grains. 

For  most  types  of  farms  there  are  no  appreciable  differences 
between  the  larger  and  smaller  farms  in  the  proportion  of  total 
farm  expenses  comprised  by  the  purchase  of  livestock  and  poultry. 
The  exception  is  found  among  livestock  farms  other  than  dairy 
and  poultry.  On  the  larger  economic  classes  for  this  type  29 
percent  of  the  total  farm  expense  was  for  purchase  of  livestock 
and  poultry  compared  with  only  12  percent  on  the  smaller  economic 


Many  more  of  the  larger  livestock  farms  purchase  cattle  and 
hogs  and  feed  them  for  resale.  In  fact,  this  causes  some  of  them 
to  be  classified  in  the  larger  economic  classes  even  though  the  net 
income  is  no  more  than  that  of  some  farmers  in  the  smaller 
economic  classes  who  raise  a  larger  part  of  their  livestock. 

Feed  for  livestock  and  poultry. — This  is  the  largest  single 
expense  item  for  commercial  farmers.  Their  feed  bill  amounted 
to  about  $1,200  per  commercial  farm  in  1955  and  made  up  17 
percent  of  the  total  expenses.  The  heaviest  users  of  purchased 
feed  were  dairy,  poultry,  and  other  livestock  farms.  The  three 
types  taken  together  accounted  for  four-fifths  of  the  feed  purchased 
by  commercial  farmers. 

Feed  purchased  was  by  far  the  most  important  expense  for 
poultry  farmers,  comprising  58  percent  of  their  total  expenses. 
A  fourth  of  the  total  expenses  of  dairy  and  general  livestock 
farmers  and  a  fifth  of  the  total  expenses  of  other  livestock  farmers 
went  for  feed. 

For  poultry,  dairy,  and  other  livestock  farms  the  expenditure 
for  feed  comprised  a  greater  proportion  of  the  total  expenses  on 
the  larger  economic  classes  of  farms.  For  other  types  (on  which 
feed  was  not  an  important  expense  item)  the  smaller  economic 
classes  had  greater  proportionate  expenses  for  feed. 

Seeds,  plants,  and  trees. — The  expenditure  for  seed,  plants, 
and  trees  made  up  only  3  percent  of  the  total  farm  expenses.  This 
ranged  from  less  than  1  percent  on  poultry  farms  to  about  6  per- 
cent on  vegetable  farms.  There  was  small  variation  between 
the  larger  and  smaller  economic  classes  of  farms  in  this  respect. 

Commercial  fertilizer  and  liming  materials. — The  average  com- 
mercial farmer  spent  $385  for  fertilizer  and  lime  in  1955.  This 
represents  less  than  6  percent  of  the  total  expenses.  The  largest 
expenditure  was  made  by  vegetable  farmers  who  averaged  $1,500 
each,  followed  by  fruit-and-nut  farmers  who  spent  $750  each. 
As  a  proportion  of  total  expenses,  however,  the  largest  share  (11 
percent)  was  spent  on  fertilizer  and  lime  by  other  field-crop  farmers. 

Of  the  total  commercial  fertilizers  and  liming  material  pur- 
chased, about  a  fifth  each  was  used  on  cash-grain  farms  and  live- 
stock farms  other  than  dairy  and  poultry.  Between  10  and  15 
percent  each  was  used  on  cotton,  other  field-crop,  and  dairy 
farms.  These  5  types  accounted  for  about  four-fifths  of  the 
fertilizers  and  liming  material  used. 


Table  46. — Percent  Distribution  of  Each  Expenditure  by  Type  of  Farm,  for  the  United  States:  1955 


Expenditure  by  economic  class  of  fan 


Other 
field- 
crop 


Total  expenditures 

Cash  w»ges... 

Machine  hire  and  customwork. 

Livestock  and  poult;  v  purchased 

Feed  for  livestock  and  poultry 

Seeds,  plants,  and  trees 

Commercial  fertiliz.-r  ami  limine;  materials 

Petroleum  product-,  tat  m  ti'riui'-s  -hare _ 

Repair  and  other  operating  costs  for  motor  vehicles  and  farm 

machinery 

Marketing  costs __. 

Miscellaneous  current  nperatine  expense,  not  incl  ided  elsewhere- 

Property  taxes,  farm  business  share 

Interest,  farm  business  share  

Construction  and  land  improvement 

Purchase  of  motor  vehicles  and  farm  machinery  and  equipment 


48 


FARMERS  AND  FARM  PRODUCTION 


Fuel,  repairs,  and  other  operating  costs  for  motor  vehicles  and 
farm  machinery. — Operating  costs  for  motor  vehicles  and  farm 
machinery  amounted  to  more  than  $1,000  per  commercial  farm 
and  comprised  nearly  15  percent  of  the  total  farm  expenses  in  1955. 
This  proportion  ranged  from  22  percent  on  cash-grain  farms  to 
only  6  percent  on  poultry  farms.  Two  types  of  farms,  cash-grain 
and  livestock  farms  other  than  dairy  and  poultry  accounted  for  more 
than  a  third  each  of  the  total  expenditure  for  operating  costs. 

For  each  type  of  farm  the  operating  costs  were  a  greater  pro- 
portion of  the  total  expenses  on  the  smaller  economic  classes  of 
farms  than  on  the  larger  ones.  The  data  are  influenced  by  the 
inclusion  of  fuel  and  upkeep  for  the  family  automobile,  an  item 
found  on  most  farms  in  1955.  Operating  costs  for  automobiles 
would  tend  to  be  greater,  relative  to  other  machinery  expenses  for 
the  smaller  farms  than  for  the  larger  ones.  However,  the  data 
are  probably  indicative  of  the  problems  encountered  by  many 
operators  of  small  farms  in  utilizing  machinery  efficiently.  In 
general,  they  have  lagged  behind  the  operators  of  larger  farms  in 
their  use  of  machinery.  But  even  at  their  present  levels  of  mech- 
anization the  smaller  farms  spent  more  proportionately  for 
operation  of  machinery  than  the  larger  ones. 

Marketing  costs. — These  amounted  to  only  5  percent  of  the 
total  farm  expenses  for  commercial  farms  as  a  group.  Marketing 
costs  were  a  more  important  expense  item  for  vegetable  farms  and 
fruit-and-nut  farms  than  other  types.  These  costs  comprised 
18  percent  and  15  percent,  respectively,  of  the  total  farm  ex- 
penses. Cotton  farmers  also  had  relatively  high  marketing  costs 
amounting  to  8  percent  of  all  expenditures. 

Miscellaneous  farm  operating  expenses. — These  include  a  num- 
ber of  expense  items  not  included  elsewhere.  The  major  items 
are  expenses  for  medicine  and  disinfectants,  pesticides,  electricity, 
telephone  service,  insurance,  hand  tools,  and  miscellaneous  farm 
business  expenses  (management  services,  recordkeeping,  legal  fees, 
advertising  expenses,  etc.). 

These  expenses  comprised  7  percent  of  the  total  cash  farm  ex- 
penses in  1955  for  commercial  farms  as  a  group.  They  were  a 
fairly  constant  proportion  of  the  total  expenses  for  most  types 
ranging  from  a  high  of  11  percent  on  fruit-and-nut  farms  to  a  low 
of  4  percent  on  vegetable  farms. 

Property  taxes  and  interest. — About  6  percent  of  the  total  cash 
expenses  of  commercial  farmers  were  for  these  expenses.  There 
was  small  variation  between  the  types  and  economic  classes  of 
farms  in  this  respect. 

Capital  expenditures. — The  total  expenditures  for  1955  included 
two  items  of  capital  expenditure:  (1)  Payment  for  construction 
and  land  improvement  and  (2)  purchase  of  motor  vehicles  and 
farm  machinery.  These  items  are  not  generally  included  in 
current  farm  operating  expenses.  Their  costs  are  more  properly 
spread  over  a  period  of  years. 

The  capital  expenditure  items  are  included  here  with  the  total 
cash  expenses,  largely  as  a  matter  of  convenience.  However,  the 
purchase  of  capital  equipment  is  largely  for  replacement  of  exist- 
ing equipment.  It  is  probable  that  the  total  cash  outlay  for 
capital  equipment  by  farmers  in  any  one  year  approximates  the 
cost  that  might  be  attributed  to  depreciation  of  all  capital  equip- 
ment on  farms  for  the  1-year  period.  It  is  an  overstatement 
of  depreciation  to  the  extent  that  these  purchases  represent  an 
increase  in  the  total  investment  of  farmers. 

The  cost  for  construction  and  land  improvements  made  up 
about  5  percent  of  the  total  cash  expenses  of  commercial  farmers. 
This  was  a  fairly  constant  proportion  of  the  total  expenses  for 


each  type  of  farm.  The  proportion  of  total  expenses  that  were 
for  construction  and  land  improvement  was  slightly  greater  on 
the  smaller  than  on  the  larger  economic  classes  for  most  types 
of  farms. 

The  purchase  of  motor  vehicles  and  farm  machinery  was  one  of 
the  largest  cash  expenses  of  commercial  farmers  in  1955,  com- 
prising 13  percent  of  the  total  cash  expenses.  This  expense  varied 
considerably  by  type  of  farm.  It  amounted  to  a  fifth  of  the  total 
expenses  of  cash-grain  farmers  and  was  the  largest  single  expense. 
Each  type  of  farm  reported  10  percent  or  more  of  the  total  cash 
expenses  for  purchase  of  motor  vehicles  and  farm  machinery 
except  vegetable  farms  and  poultry  farms. 

The  proportion  of  total  expenses  that  went  for  purchase  of 
motor  vehicles  and  farm  machinery  was  much  greater  on  the 
smaller  economic  classes  of  farms  than  on  the  larger  ones — half 
again  to  twice  as  much  for  most  types  of  farms. 

Total  Motor  Vehicle  and  Machinery  Expenses 

When  the  costs  for  purchase  of  motor  vehicles  and  farm  ma- 
chinery are  added  to  the  expenses  for  fuel,  repairs,  and  other 
operating  costs,  it  is  apparent  that  these  comprised  the  major 
cash  expenditure  of  commercial  farmers  in  1955.  The  expenses 
for  purchase  and  operation  of  motor  vehicles  and  farm  ma- 
chinery are  shown  as  a  proportion  of  the  total  cash  expenses  in 
table  47.  These  costs  made  up  28  percent  of  the  total  cash  ex- 
penses of  commercial  farmers.  They  comprised  from  a  fourth 
to  two-fifths  of  the  total  on  all  except  vegetable,  fruit-and-nut, 
and  poultry  farms. 

Table  47- — Expenses  for  Purchase  and  Operation  of  Motor 
Vehicles,  Farm  Machinery,  and  Equipment  '  as  a  Per' 
centage  of  total  farm  expenditure,  by  type  and  eco' 
nomic  Class  of  Commercial  Farm,  for  the  United  States: 
1955 


Total 

Economic  class 
of  farm 

Type  of  farm 

I  and  II 

III 

thrnu^l: 

VI 

27.7 
42.1 
32.3 
29.7 
16.3 

20.7 
28.7 
10.2 
22.7 

30.6 
31.6 
32.0 
17.0 

Percent 

39^2 
27.0 
19.0 
13.4 

17.0 

8.0 

18.0 

26.2 
27.8 
26.4 
11.6 

Percent 

General: 

On  the  smaller  economic  classes  the  proportions  were  even 
higher,  accounting  for  a  third  or  more  of  the  total  expenses  for 
most  types  of  farms.  In  Economic  Classes  III  through  VI  motor 
vehicle  and  machinery  costs  amounted  to  45  percent  of  the  total 
cash  farm  expenses  for  cash-grain  farmers  and  39  percent  for 
cotton  and  other  field-crop  farmers. 


A  GENERAL  VIEW 


49 


Census  Specified   Expenses 

The  1954  Census  of  Agriculture  obtained  data  on  the  following 
farm  expenditure  items:  Hired  labor,  machine  hire,  feed  for 
livestock  and  poultry,  gasoline  and  other  petroleum  fuel  and  oil, 
and  commercial  fertilizers  and  liming  material.  The  individual 
expense  items  obtained  by  the  Census  for  type  by  economic  class 
of  farm  are  not  shown  separately  in  this  chapter  but  appear  in 
volume  III,  part  8,  of  the  Census  of  Agriculture. 

The  average  per  farm  of  the  total  specified  expenses  and  the 
proportion  they  comprise  of  the  total  value  of  farm  products  sold 
are  shown  for  each  type  of  farm  by  economic  class  in  table  48. 
By  type  of  farm  the  average  expenditure  ranged  from  about 
$1,300  for  other  field-crop  farms  to  over  $7,000  for  vegetable  and 
poultry  farms.  The  specified  farm  expenses  amounted  to  37 
percent  of  the  value  of  farm  products  sold  for  commercial  farms 
as  a  group,  but  this  varied  considerably  by  type  of  farm — from 
a  fourth  on  cash-grain  farms  to  nearly  three-fourths  on  poultry 
farms.  Also,  the  specified  expenses  were  higher,  relative  to  sales, 
on  the  smaller  economic  classes  of  farms  for  most  types.  This  is 
influenced  by  the  higher  proportion  of  the  farm  products  pro- 
duced on  these  farms  that  are  consumed  in  the  home  rather  than 
sold. 


Table  48. — Specified  Farm  Expenses,  Average  per  Farm  and 
as  a  Percentage  of  the  Total  Value  of  Farm  Products 
Sold,  by  Type  of  Farm  by  Economic  Class,  for  the 
United  States:  1954 


Specified  expenses  per  farm:  ' 

All  commercial  farms dolla 

Cash-grain do. 

Cotton... do. 

Other  field-crop do. 

Vegetable do. 

Fruit-and-nut do. 

Dairy. do 

Poultry... do. 

Livestock  other  than  dairy  a 
poultry dolla 

General: 
Primarily  crop do. 

Primarily  livestock do. 

Crop  and  livestock do. 

Miscellaneous do. 


Specified  expenses  as  a  percent   of 
the  value  of  farm  products  sold : 

All  commercial  farms percent-. 

Cash-grain... do 

Cotton _ do 

Other  field-crop do 

Vegetable do 

Fruit-and-nut do 

Dairy do 

Poultry ...do 

Livestock  other  than  dairy  and 
poultry percent.. 


General: 

Primarily  crop _ 

Primarily  livestock. 
Crop  and  livestock.. 

Miscellaneous 


Ki-oni.mic  class  nf  1  u  in 


.'1,'JnH 

l!i.  4' hi 
II,.  m,.-, 
'-'.-,,1,74 


II         III       IV 


1  Includes  the  following  expenses:  Cash  wages,  machine  hire,  feed  for  livestock  and 
poultry,  fuel  and  other  petroleum  products,  and  commercial  fertilizer  and  liming 
materials. 


Relation  of  Census  Specified  Expenses  to  Total  Farm  Expenses 

The  1954  Census  of  Agriculture  obtained  specified  farm  ex- 
penses for  the  year  1954.  Data  from  the  Farm  Expenditure 
Survey  relate  to  1955.  Because  of  the  different  years  involved 
the  two  series  of  data  may  not  be  compared  directly.  However, 
in  the  light  of  data  from  the  Farm  Expenditure  Survey  it  is 
possible  to  make  a  meaningful  evaluation  of  the  Census  specified 
expenses  to  appraise  how  representative  they  are  of  total  ex- 
penses. For  this  purpose,  the  categories  of  expenses  from  the 
Farm  Expenditure  Survey  which  correspond  to  the  Census  speci- 
fied items  have  been  computed  as  a  proportion  of  total  current 
cash  expenses  (exclusive  of  capital  expenditures).  These  per- 
centages for  types  of  farms  by  specified  economic  classes  are 
shown  in  table  49. 

On  the  basis  of  relationships  from  the  Farm  Expenditure  Sur- 
vey, the  farm  expenses  obtained  by  the  1954  Census  of  Agriculture 
comprised  slightly  more  than  half  of  the  total  cash  farm  expenses 
of  commercial  farmers.  The  Census  specified  expenses  accounted 
for  a  high  of  approximately  three-fourths  of  the  total  expenses 
for  poultry  farmers  and  nearly  three-fifths  for  those  of  cotton, 
other  field-crop,  dairy,  and  general  livestock  farmers.  In  con- 
trast, these  expenses  amounted  to  less  than  half  of  the  total 
expenses  of  cash-grain  and  other  livestock  producers. 

There  was  little  difference  in  tins  respect  between  the  two  size 
groups  for  most  types  of  farms.  Notable  exceptions  are  dairy 
farms  and  other  livestock  farms.  Among  dairy  farms  the  Census 
specified  expenses  accounted  for  a  greater  proportion  of  total  ex- 
penses for  the  larger  economic  classes.  This  was  due  partly  to  the 
higher  expenditure  for  feed  reported  by  the  larger  farms.  For 
other  livestock  farms  the  Census  specified  expenses  comprised  a 
greater  proportion  of  total  expenses  on  the  smaller  economic 
classes.  This  was  partly  because  the  Census  specified  expenses 
did  not  include  the  expense  for  purchase  of  livestock  and  poultry. 
As  mentioned  previously,  this  was  a  much  more  important  ex- 
pense on  the  larger  than  on  the  smaller  economic  classes  of  farms. 


Table  49. — Specified  Group  of  Farm  Expense  Items  as  a 
Percentage  of  the  Total  Cash  Farm  Expenses,  by  Type 
of  Farm  by  Economic  Class,  for  the  United  States:  1955  ' 


Total 

Economic  class  of 
farm 

Type  of  farm 

I  and  II 

III 

through 

Percent 
54.2 
48.6 
57.8 
58.9 
51.5 

53.9 
69.3 
73.9 
46.8 

55.2 
57.7 
62.2 
66.9 

Percent 
53.8 
49.3 

66.8 
57.8 
52.8 

53.0 
64.7 
75.9 
43.4 

53.1 
61.7 
51.0 
68.2 

Percent 

General: 

'  The  following  expenses,  cash  wages,  machine  hue  f 1  foi  livestock  and  poultry, 

fuel  and  other  petroleum  jiroilucts,  and  commercial  fertilizer  and  liming  materials, 
were  divided  by  the  total  cash  farm  .  \|,eiis,  s  lexchcUng  those  foi  construction,  land 
improvement,  and  purchase  of  motor  vehicles,  farm  machinery  and  equipment). 


50 


FARMERS  AND  FARM  PRODUCTION 


Estimated  Value  Added 

It  is  not  possible  with  existing  data  to  make  precise  determina- 
tions of  productivity  and  returns  for  types  and  economic  classes 
of  commercial  farms.  There  are  several  important  limitations. 
Foremost  of  these  is  that  the  specified  farm  expenses  obtained  in 
the  Census  of  1954  are  not  equally  representative  of  total  expenses 
for  different  types  and  economic  classes  of  farms.  An  additional 
limitation  is  that  data  on  farm  sales  obtained  by  the  Census  are 
not  complete,  largely  because  of  omissions  by  farmers  in  the 
reporting  of  sales  of  livestock  and  livestock  products.  Still 
another  limitation  relates  to  the  fact  that  the  classifications  of 
farms  by  type  and  by  economic  class  are  based  on  the  value  of 
farm  products  sold  in  the  particular  year  1954.  Thus,  a  farm's 
type  or  economic  class  is  affected  by  any  abnormalities  in  yields 
or  sales  from  inventories  as  well  as  the  relative  price  relationships 
between  commodities  in  1954. 

Notwithstanding  these  limitations,  an  attempt  has  been  made 
here  to  estimate  differences  between  types  and  economic  classes 
of  farms  in  the  value  of  farm  products  sold  minus  the  cost  of  the 
material  and  contract  services  used  in  producing  the  products. 
This  is  an  approximation  of  the  value  added  by  agriculture  and 
will  be  referred  to  hereafter  as  value  added. 

The  estimate  of  value  added  was  made  in  order  to  provide 
additional  insight  into  the  structural  differences  in  farming. 
Technological  changes  in  farming  have  brought  about  a  sub- 
stantial increase  in  farm  production  but  this  has  been  accompanied 
by  larger  cash  costs  in  farming.  Farmers  now  purchase  many 
materials  for  use  in  further  production  that  they  formerly  pro- 
duced for  themselves.  The  value  of  products  sold  is  not  a  satis- 
factory measure  of  the  relative  productivity  of  a  given  type  or 
size  of  farm  because  only  a  part  of  this  value  is  actually  created 
within  the  farm.  Value  added,  as  used  here,  attempts  to  correct 
for  the  widely  different  input-output  relationships  that  exist  in 
respect  to  types  and  sizes  of  farms.  It  is  thought  that  the  esti- 
mate of  value  added  may  be  useful  for  a  broad  appraisal  of  pro- 
ductivity differentials  within  the  various  segments  of  commercial 
agriculture. 

In  developing  the  estimate  of  value  added,  the  Census  specified 
expenses  (excluding  cash  wages)  were  expanded  to  reflect  several 
additional  expense  items.  The  expansion  was  made  on  the  basis 
of  data  from  the  Farm  Expenditure  Survey,  discussed  previously. 
The  adjusted  expenses  for  each  type  and  economic  class  of  farm 
were  then  subtracted  from  the  total  value  of  farm  products  sold. 

The  Census  expense  items — machine  hire,  feed  for  livestock 
and  poultry,  gasoline  and  other  petroleum  fuel  and  oil,  and  com- 
mercial fertilizer  and  liming  materials — were  expanded  to  include 
expenditures  for  the  following  items:  Livestock  and  poultry, 
seeds,  plants  and  trees,  and  repairs  and  other  operating  costs  for 
motor  vehicles  and  farm  machinery.  The  factor  used  in  expanding 
the  Census  expense  items  was  the  percentage  the  former  4  items 
comprised  of  the  larger  category  of  7  items  as  determined  by  data 
from  the  Farm  Expenditure  Survey.  These  percentages  for  each 
type  of  commercial  farm  are  as  follows: 


Type  of  farm 

S" 

Type  of  farm 

sion 

Percent 

56^8 
61.8 
64.9 

67^7 
74.3 

80.4 

All  commercial  farms— Con. 
Livestock  uihcr  than  dairy 
and  poultry. 

General,  primarily  crop 

General.  priinunh  livestock 
General,  crop  ami  livestock. 

Percent 

62.3 

Vegetable 

71.0 

The  totals  of  the  Census  expense  items  (excluding  cash  wages) 
for  each  type  of  farm  by  economic  class  were  divided  by  the 
percentages  shown  in  the  previous  table.  The  expanded  expendi- 
ture data  were  then  subtracted  from  the  value  of  farm  products 
sold. 

It  will  be  noted  that  the  farm  expenses,  as  adjusted,  do  not 
include  several  items  commonly  included  in  current  cash  expenses; 
namely,  marketing  charges,  interest,  taxes,  and  other  miscella- 
neous expenses.  Interest  and  taxes  are  quite  properly  excluded 
from  the  value  added  concept.  These  are  charges  to  capital  and 
do  not  represent  materials  used  in  further  production.  Marketing 
cost  and  other  miscellaneous  farm  expenses  would  normally  be 
deducted. 

Marketing  costs  were  omitted  because  of  the  possible  duplication 
of  this  expense  in  the  value  of  farm  products  sold.  The  total 
value  of  farm  products,  as  reported  by  the  Census,  has  some  of 
the  marketing  charges  deducted.  Farmers,  in  reporting  their 
sales  of  farm  products  are  likely  to  report  the  value  received  after 
freight,  handling,  and  commission  charges  have  been  deducted. 
Under  the  procedure  employed  by  the  Census  of  Agriculture,  each 
farmer  was  asked  to  report  the  value  of  livestock,  livestock  prod- 
ucts, vegetables,  horticultural  specialities,  and  forestry  products 
sold.  It  is  believed  that  the  values  reported  for  these  products 
tend  to  have  a  large  part  of  the  marketing  costs  deducted.  On 
the  other  hand,  for  field  crops  and  .fruits  and  nuts,  each  farmer 
reported  the  quantity  sold  and  the  market  value  was  computed 
as  part  of  the  office  procedure  by  applying  average  unit  prices. 
Values  computed  on  this  basis  would  more  nearly  represent 
market  values  before  any  deduction. 

Miscellaneous  farm  expenses  (not  included  elsewhere)  were 
excluded  from  the  estimate  because  this  category  is  composed  of 
a  large  variety  of  minor  items.  Some  of  these  include  expenses 
not  attributable  to  the  farm  business;  others  are  capital  and 
management  services  whose  inclusion  would  be  questionable.  It 
was  believed  that  exclusion  of  this  category  would  not  affect 
greatly  the   comparability  of  the   estimates  between  types   and 

The  value  added  per  farm  is  shown  in  table  50.  Value  added, 
as  estimated  here,  amounted  to  $4,088  per  commercial  farm  in 
1954.  This  was  56  percent  of  the  gross  value  of  farm  products 
sold.  By  type  of  farm,  value  added  was  highest  for  vegetable  and 
fruit-and-nut  farms,  averaging  about  $12,000  per  farm.  These 
types  were  also  highest  in  the  average  value  of  farm  products 
sold.  (See  table  26  for  comparisons.)  Poultry  farms,  also  among 
the  highest  in  the  average  value  of  farm  products  sold,  were 
lowest  in  the  value  added,  averaging  only  $1,300  per  farm.  Most 
other  types  ranged  between  $3,000  and  $5,000  in  value  added. 

Table  50. — Estimated  Value  Added  per  Farm  by  Type  of 
Farm  by  Economic  Class,  for  the  United  States:  1954 


Total 

Economic  class  of  farm 

1 

II 

III 

IV 

V 

VI 

All  commercial  farms 

Dollars 

1.IISS 

'i.  53.1 

3,011(1 
11,553 

12,  146 
3,  303 
1,324 
3,936 

4.742 
2,556 

3.  2117 
10,  749 

Hollo, x 
37,  155 
31,0111 
52,  S01 
45.  (US 

76,956 

25!  53 1' 
11.  432 
32,  230 

47,  787 

10,  12S 
311.720 

62, 101 

Hollo, s 
s,  317 
10.010 
Id.  lino 

10,  40S 
10,561 

13,  510 
7,493 
1,966 
7,309 

8,716 

7,568 
8,  10,4 
12,051 

Ihilhrs 

3.  700 
4.431 

4,  720 
4.  SSS 
4,336 

6,273 

3,679 

604 

2,813 

3,909 

3,0(10 
3,  S12 

Dollars 
1.S37 
2.015 
2.  373 
2.  651 
1,960 

3,146 

1,819 

151 

943 

1,814 

1.5*10 
1,607 
2,079 

Dollar* 

709 
1,  168 
1,317 

739 

1,421 
765 
114 

769 
576 
606 
849 

nollars 
217 
96 

421 

501 

160 

Fruil-and-nut 

210 

(') 

w 

General: 

Primarily  crop 

250 
135 

142 

164 

the  value  of  farm  products  t 


A  GENERAL  VIEW 


51 


Among  farms  in  each  economic  class  there  is  much  greater 
variation  between  types  in  the  value  added  than  in  the  total  value 
of  farm  products  sold.  Value  added,  as  a  proportion  of  total 
sales,  varies  considerably  between  types  of  farms  for  each  economic 
class  (see  table  51).  It  is  highest  on  fruit-and-nut  farms  for  each 
economic  class  of  farm.  In  general,  value  added  was  a  higher 
proportion  of  the  gross  sales  for  farms  with  a  major  source  of 
income  from  sales  of  field  crops  and  vegetables  than  for  livestock 
types.  It  comprised  the  lowest  proportion  of  gross  sales  on  poul- 
try farms. 

Value  added  was  a  greater  proportion  of  farm  sales  on  the  larger 
than  on  the  smaller  economic  classes  of  farms  for  each  type. 
This  is  influenced  to  a  large  extent  by  the  measure  of  value  added 
being  based  upon  farm  products  sold  rather  than  the  total  value 
of  products  produced.  On  the  smaller  economic  classes  of  far  ms 
a  substantial  part  of  the  production  is  consumed  on  the  farm. 

Table  51. — Estimated  Value  Added  as  a  Percent  of  th 
Total  Value  of  Farm  Products  Sold,  by  Type  of  Farm  by 
Economic  Class:  1954 


Type  of  farm 

Total 

Economic  class  of  farm 

I 

II 

III 

IV 

V 

VI 

All  commercial  farms 

Per- 

V.o'u 
64.6 
71.3 
71.1 
72.0 

84.3 
50.6 
13.7 
44.6 

64.4 

52^8 
81.5 

Per- 
cent 

75' 9 
75.8 
75.6 
76.0 

86.8 
50.9 
19.1 
55.4 

73.0 
48.2 
64.7 
87.5 

Per- 

67^7 
70.7 
69.7 
68.3 

84.0 

52.8 
12.5 
47.9 

64.7 
53.0 
57.8 
79.7 

Per- 

52.4 
60.6 
69.6 
70.7 
61.6 

80.4 
51.8 
8.2 
38.6 

59.4 
50.5 
53.2 

71.2 

Per- 
cent 
49.6 
52.4 
69.4 
71.3 
56.1 

76.6 
48.6 
4.0 
25.2 

53.2 
40.5 

58^8 

Per- 
il. 1 
66  2 
68.4 
42.5 

69.6 
40.6 
6.1 

7.8 

45.0 
30.5 
32.3 
46.4 

Per- 
28.7 

62.2 

General: 

Primarily  crop 

34.0 

>  Expenses  exceeded  the  value  of  farm  products  sold. 

Value  added  per  man- equivalent. — When  converted  to  a  man- 
equivalent  basis,  value  added  becomes  a  reasonably  good  measure 
of  labor  productivity.  At  prevailing  levels  of  prices  for  farm 
products  and  costs  of  materials  used  in  further  production,  it  is  a 
measure  of  efficiency  in  the  use  of  labor  resources.  Value  added 
per  man-equivalent  amounted  to  $2,800  for  commercial  farms  as 
a  group.  (See  table  52.)  It  was  highest  on  fruit-and-nut  and 
cash-grain    farms,    averaging    $4,900    and    $4,400,    respectively. 

Table  52. — Estimated  Value  Added  per  Man-Equivalent  by 
Type  of  Farm,  by  Economic  Class,  for  the  United  States: 
1954 


Total 

Economic  class  of  farm 

I 

II 

III 

IV 

v 

VI 

All  commercial  farms 

111,11,1, / 
2.  Mill 
4..SM 
2.  (Ml 
2.  Dili 
3,236 

4,939 

2.  2-14 
1,141 

2,945 

1,'Jsl 
2,4117 
3,937 

Il,,U,l,.s 

(',,  X55 
11.271 
0.x]  2 
''.241 
4,318 

6,330 

4.  703 

3,  4x11 
9,856 

6,026 
5.047 
7,li:i7 
5,053 

ll,,U„r.s 

4.1.12 
('.,  1.2:1 
4,345 
4,301 
2,941 

5,136 

:i,  mm 
1.375 
4,540 

4,211 
4.478 
4,f.'.l2 
4,304 

Dollars 

2. 629 

3,1.112 
2,440 
2,  731 
2,168 

3,896 

2,  520 

534 

2,115 

2,555 

2.  539 
2.  0X4 
2,936 

Ih,ll:,,,. 

1,440 
2,015 
1,412 
1,767 
1,371 

2,809 

1,455 

161 

842 

1,451 

1,195 
1,275 
1,792 

Dollars 
750 
854 
834 
1,0X8 
684 

1,652 
729 
148 
164 

769 
549 
566 
987 

Dollars 

General: 

Primarily  crop.... 

260 

Expenses  exceeded  the  value  of  farm  products  sold. 


Most  other  types  of  farms  ranged  between  $2,000  and  $3,000 
value  added  per  man-equivalent.  The  exception  was  poultry 
farms  with  about  $1,100  per  man-equivalent. 

Value  added  per  man-equivalent  was  highest  for  Class  I  farms 
of  each  type  and  decreased  with  each  successively  smaller  eco- 
nomic class.  On  Classes  V  and  VI  farms  it  was  far  below  the 
average  for  commercial  farms  as  a  group. 

Value  added  per  $1,000  of  capital  investment. — This  is  a 
measure  of  efficiency  in  the  use  of  capital  resources.  The  value 
added  was  divided  by  the  total  investment  in  land  and  buildings, 
machinery  and  equipment,  and  livestock  inventory.  This  is 
expressed  in  terms  of  value  added  for  each  $1,000  of  total  capital 
investment  in  table  53. 

In  general,  farms  with  a  major  source  of  income  from  fruits 
and  nuts,  vegetables,  and  field  crops  had  a  higher  product  added 
per  unit  of  capital  used  than  types  with  a  major  source  of  income 
from  livestock  and  livestock  products.  The  exception  was  cash- 
grain  farms. 


Table  53. — Estimated  Value  Added  per  $1,000  of  Capital 
Investment  in  Land  and  Buildings,  Machinery  and  Live- 
stock  Inventory,  by  Type  of  Farm  by  Economic  Class,  for 
the  United  States:  1954 


Total 

Economic  class  of  farm 

I 

II 

III 

IV 

V 

VI 

All  commercial  farms 

Dull, us 
124 
110 
222 
238 
257 

235 
127 

74 
80 

132 
92 
97 

326 

Dollars 

183 

271 
339 
351 

318 
203 
213 
168 

218 
172 

188 

Dollars 
127 
124 
186 
231 
197 

219 
149 
83 
93 

128 
139 
124 
256 

Dollars 
102 
96 

244 
139 

170 
126 
35 
59 

108 
104 
96 
161 

Dollars 
86 

214 
241 
98 

122 
95 

29 

65 
64 
99 

Dollars 
62 
39 
195 
188 

70 
58 

6 

50 
36 

52 

Dollars 
27 

General: 

Expenses  exceed.:.!  the  value  uf  farm  products  sold 


Cash-grain  farms,  among  the  highest  in  value  added  per  man- 
equivalent,  were  among  the  lowest  in  value  added  per  unit  of  total 
investment.  Cotton  and  other  field-crop  farms  were  among  the 
lowest  in  value  added  per  man-equivalent  but  were  relatively  high 
in  value  added  per  capital  investment.  For  fruit-and-nut  farms 
the  value  added  was  relatively  high  on  both  bases.  It  was  rela- 
tively low  on  both  bases  for  dairy,  poultry,  and  other  livestock 
farms. 


By  economic  class  of  farm  the  value  added  per  unit  of  total 
investment  is  highest  on  Class  I  farms  and  decreases  with  each 
successively  smaller  economic  class.  For  most  types,  however, 
the  differences  between  economic  classes  are  relatively  small 
compared  to  the  substantial  differences  between  these  classes  in 
the  value  added  per  man-equivalent. 

Due  to  the  limitations  involved  in  making  these  estimates,  no 
precise  conclusion  may  be  drawn  regarding  the  specific  amounts 
of  value  added  per  man-equivalent  or  per  dollar  of  investment. 
However,  it  appears  reasonable  to  conclude  that  (1)  value  added 
per  man-equivalent  and  per  dollar  of  investment  is  extremely  low 
on  the  smaller  economic  classes  of  farms;  low  in  relation  to  agri- 
culture as  a  whole  and  also  in  relation  to  that  obtained  in  nonfarm 
sectors  of  the  economy  and  (2)  for  any  given  type  of  farm  their 
amounts  are  directly  associated  with  the  size  of  the  farm  business. 


52 


FARMERS  AND  FARM  PRODUCTION 


Home  Facilities 

The  measures  of  value  added,  discussed  previously,  are  useful 
primarily  in  showing  efficiency  differentials  in  agriculture.  They 
are  not  measures  of  farm  income.  However,  due  to  the  small 
volume  of  sales  (and  lesser  amounts  of  value  added)  on  the  smaller 
economic  classes  of  farms,  it  is  probable  that  incomes  from  farming 
are  fairly  low. 

An  indirect  measure  of  income  is  found  in  the  levels  of  living  of 
farm-operator  families  as  indicated  by  home  facilities.  The  data 
and  discussion  which  follow  relate  some  of  these  to  types  and 
economic  classes  of  farms. 

Electricity. — Most  of  rural  America  had  electricity  in  the  homes 
in  1954 — nearly  94  percent  of  all  commercial  farms.  (See  table 
54.)  More  than  90  percent  of  each  type  of  farm  except  cotton 
reported  electricity.  Among  farms  of  each  type  the  proportion 
reporting  electricity  decreased  with  decreasing  size  of  farm  (meas- 
ured by  gross  sales  of  farm  products).  Even  on  Class  VI  farms, 
however,  more  than  four-fifths  of  each  type  reported  electricity, 
except  cotton  farms,  of  which  about  three-fourths  had  electricity 
in  the  homes. 

Table  54. — Percent  of  Farms  Reporting  Electricity  by 
Type  of  Farm  by  Economic  Class,  for  the  United  States: 
1954 


Type  of  farm 

Total 

Economic  class  of  farm 

I 

n 

III 

rv 

V 

VI 

93. 8 
94.2 
86.8 
91.8 
94.1 

93.6 
97.3 
97.6 

95.0 

93.4 
95.3 
97.0 
94.6 

97.5 
97.3 
97.1 
97.5 
92.7 

96.5 
99.3 
98.9 

97.3 

98.1 
100.0 
98.4 
98.1 

97.9 
97.6 
97.1 
98.1 
96.9 

912 
98.6 
99.3 

98.0 

97.8 
96.9 
98.8 
96.7 

97.4 
96.1 
96.2 
97.5 
96.9 

94.0 
99.1 
98.3 

97.2 

96.9 
96.2 
98.4 
96.9 

95.6 
94.1 
92.0 

9&  8 

92.5 
98.3 
97.8 

95.6 

95.0 
96.5 
99.2 
95.1 

91.2 

89.5 
86.4 
90.4 
94.1 

92.8 
95.7 
97.6 

93.2 

91.5 
95.8 
93.1 

84.2 

84.4 

76.3 

82.2 

89.3 

91.6 

V.I  0 

94.3 

Livestock    other    than    dairy    and 

88.8 

General: 

83.7 

KH  5 

89.9 

Index  of  home  facilities. — The  1954  Census  of  Agriculture 
obtained  information  relating  to  whether  certain  facilities  and 
conveniences  were  in  the  farm  home.  The  existence  of  these 
facilities  in  farm  homes  provides  a  general  indication  of  levels 
of  household  living.  As  a  means  of  comparing  the  relative  extent 
to  which  operator  families  on  different  types  and  economic  classes 
of  farms  have  been  able  to  have  these  home  conveniences,  they 
have  been  summarized  into  an  index  of  home  facilities.  (See 
table  55.) 

The  index  is  based  on  the  following  items:  Telephone,  television, 
piped  running  water,  home  freezer,  and  automobile.  Electricity 
in  the  home  was  not  included  since  several  of  the  other  items  are 
directly  related  to  the  availability  of  electricity  there  and  it  is 
known  that  electricity  is  now  available  in  most  of  the  farm- 
operator  homes.     The  automobile  is  not  thought  of  as  a  household 


facility  in  the  same  sense  as  the  other  items.  As  a  means  of 
transportation,  however,  it  represents  a  convenience  that  is  im- 
portant in  indicating  relative  levels  of  living. 

In  computing  the  index,  the  sum  of  the  farms  reporting  each 
item  for  each  type  and  class  of  farm  was  divided  by  the  total 
number  of  farms  in  the  group.  On  this  basis  the  highest  possible 
score  (if  each  farm  in  the  group  reported  each  item)  was  5.  The 
score  obtained  for  each  type  and  economic  class  of  farm  was  then 
divided  by  the  score  for  all  commercial  farms;  thus,  the  index  is 
constructed  to  show  each  type  and  economic  class  of  farm  as  a 
percentage  of  the  average  for  all  commercial  farms. 

Table  55. — Index  of  Specified  Home  Facilities,  Commercial 
Farms  By  Economic  Class  and  Type,  for  the  United  States: 
1954 

[Total  commercial  farms=100  >1 


Total 

Economic  class  of  farm 

I 

II 

III 

IV 

V 

VI 

100 
117 
48 

125 
121 
120 

116 

97 
115 
111 
114 

153 
153 
147 
152 
145 

150 
166 
152 

155 

154 
165 
160 
147 

145 
143 
122 
132 
150 

140 
157 
135 

147 

137 
152 
149 
139 

124 

83 
89 
134 

130 

140 
125 

129 

111 
133 
127 
128 

96 
106 
61 
62 
119 

120 
117 
119 

113 

90 
112 
105 
113 

75 
98 
36 
50 
104 

113 
94 
116 

101 

81 
95 
87 
101 

65 

Livestock    other    than    dairy    and 

General: 

63 

(fit 

1  Index  based  on  farms  report  ing  1  or  more  of  the  following  items  of  specified  facilities 
and  equipment:  Telephone,  television  set,  piped  running  water,  home  freezer,  and 
automobile. 


With  the  exception  of  cotton  and  other  field-crop  farms,  each 
type  of  farm  was  above  or  approximately  equal  to  the  average  for 
all  commercial  farms.  The  indexes  of  48  on  cotton  farms  and  60 
on  other  field-crop  farms  indicate  that  these  farms  reported  only 
about  half  as  many  of  the  specified  facilities  as  most  other  types. 

Within  each  type  of  farm  the  level  of  home  conveniences  was 
related  to  economic  class  of  farm.  This  is  to  be  expected  since  the 
economic  classification  based  upon  gross  sales  may  indicate 
roughly  relative  levels  of  income.  Home  facilities  and  conven- 
iences depend  largely  upon  the  incomes  the  families  on  these 
farms  have  at  their  disposal.  For  most  types  of  farms  the  opera- 
tors on  Class  V  and  Class  VI  farms  reported  only  one-fourth  to 
one-third  as  many  of  the  specified  items. 

The  fact  of  fewer  home  facilities  on  cotton  and  other  field-crop 
farms  is  due  chiefly  to  the  much  larger  proportion  of  these  types 
that  fall  in  the  smaller  economic  classes.  Classes  I  and  II  cotton 
and  other  field-crop  farms  have  an  index  that  is  fairly  similar  to  the 
commercial  farm  average  for  these  classes.  For  Classes  III 
through  VI,  however,  the  indexes  for  cotton  and  other  field-crop 
farms  were  substantially  below  the  indexes  for  these 
among  other  types.