Skip to main content

Full text of "Wage theory and growth theory"

See other formats


UNIVERSITY  OF 

ILLINOIS  LIBRARY 

AT  URBANA-CHAMPAIGN 

BOOKSTACKS 


be  charged  a  ntintmu^t°Y:  You  "«/ 


JAN  0  4  2000 


NOVie 


1999 


L162 


BEBR 

FACULTY  WORKING 
PAPER  NO.  1521 


IfnLr  Ml 


Wage  Theory  and  Growth  Theory 


Hans  Br  ems 


10V 


College  of  Commerce  and  Business  Administration 
Bureau  of  Economic  and  Business  Research 
University  of  Illinois.  Urbana-Champaign 


BEBR 


FACULTY  WORKING  PAPER  NO.  1521 

College  of  Commerce  and  Business  Administration 

University  of  Illinois  at  Urbana- Champaign 

December  1988 


Wage  Theory  and  Growth  Theory 

Hans  Brems ,  Professor 
Department  of  Economics 


Digitized  by  the  Internet  Archive 

in  2011  with  funding  from 

University  of  Illinois  Urbana-Champaign 


http://www.archive.org/details/wagetheorygrowth1521brem 


(217)  344-0171 
1103  South  Douglas  Avenue    Urbana,  Illinois  61801 


WAGE  THEORY  AND  GROWTH  THEORY 

HANS  BREMS 

Abstract 
According  to  the  "natural"  rate  hypothesis  in  the  short  run,  by 
accepting  a  "natural"  rate  of  less  than  full  employment,  labor  can 
have  a  real  wage  rate  higher  than  under  full  employment.  To  see  that 
hypothesis  in  a  long-run  perspective  the  paper  solves  a  neoclassical 
growth  model  for  capital  stock.,  output,  and  factor  prices  and  finds 
that  in  the  long  run,  by  accepting  a  "natural"  rate  of  less  than  full 
employment,  labor  can  have  a  real  wage  rate  no  higher  than  under  full 
employment:   levels  of  capital  stock  and  output  are  correspondingly 
lower.   Nobody  benefits. 


Under  profit  maximization,  pure  competition,  and  a  given  capital 
stock,  demand  for  labor  is  simply  labor's  marginal-productivity  curve. 
As  a  result,  in  the  short  run,  by  accepting  a  "natural"  rate  of  less 
than  full  employment,  labor  can  have  a  real  wage  rate  higher  than 
under  full  employment. 


-2- 

But  only  In  Che  short  run  may  capital  stock  be  considered  given. 
The  purpose  of  the  paper  is  to  examine  how  much  of  such  a  short-run 
wage-employment  tradeoff  will  survive  once  capital  stock  has  become  a 
variable.   We  shall  solve  a  neoclassical  growth  model  for  its  capital 
stock,  output,  and  factor  prices  and  examine  the  sensitivities  of  such 
solutions  to  a  "natural"  rate  of  less  than  full  employment.   The  model 
is  this. 


I.   THE  MODEL 


1.  Variables 

C  =  physical  consumption 

g  =  proportionate  rate  of  growth  of  variable  v 

I  =  physical  investment 

<  =  physical  marginal  productivity  of  capital  stock 

L  =  labor  employed 

P  =  price  of  goods  and  services 

r  =  nominal  rate  of  interest 

p  =  real  rate  of  interest 


-3- 

S  =  physical  capital  stock 

w  =  money  wage  rate 

X  5  physical  output 

Y  =  money  national  income 

2.  Parameters 

a  E  multiplicative  factor  of  production  function 
a, 8  =  exponents  of  production  function 
c  =  propensity  to  consume 
F  =  available  labor  force 

X  =  "natural"  fraction  of  available  labor  force  employed 
M  E  supply  of  money 

V  =  velocity  of  money 

3 .  National  Income 

Money  national  income  defined  as  the  aggregate  earnings  arising 
from  current  production  is  identically  equal  to  national  product 
defined  as  the  market  value  of  physical  output: 

Y  =  PX  (1) 


-4- 
4.   Production  Function 

We  must  be  careful  with  our  aggregation  and  begin  at  the  firm 
level.   Let  the  inputs  of  an  individual  firm  be  labor  L  and  physical 
capital  stock  S  and  its  physical  output  be  X.   Then  let  a  Cobb-Douglas 
production  function  be  common  to  all  firms: 


X  =  aLaS8  (2) 


where  0  <  a  <  1,  0  <  8  <  1,  a  +  8  =  1>  and  a  is  what  growth  measurement 
[Maddison  (1987:   658)]  calls  "joint  factor  productivity." 

5.   Demand  for  Labor 

Demand  for  labor  is  a  short-run  commitment  to  be  determined  by 
maximization  of  profits.   Here  the  firm  may  consider  its  physical 
capital  stock.  S  a  constant  and  ignore  the  effect  of  investment  I  upon 
it.   Maximizing  its  gross  profits  PX  -  wL  with  respect  to  employment 
L,  the  firm  will  then  hire  labor  until  the  last  man  costs  as  much  as 
he  contributes,  and  under  pure  competition  the  real  wage  rate  will 
then  equal  the  physical  marginal  productivity  of  labor: 


-5- 


w    3X  - 

-  =  —  =  aaLa  "  1S6  (3) 

P    8L 


Since  a  +  S  =  1,  a  -  1  =  -  B,  so  raise  to  power  -1/B,  rearrange, 
and  write  firm  demand  for  labor 


-1/B 

P 


w 
L  =  (aa)1/B(-)     S  (4) 


On  the  right-hand  side  of  (4)  everything  except  S  is  common  to  all 
firms.   Factor  out  all  such  common  factors  and  sum  (4)  over  firms. 
Then  S  becomes  aggregate  physical  capital  stock  and  L  aggregate  demand 
for  labor. 

6.   Supply  of  Labor 

Current  labor-market  literature,  e.g.,  Lindbeck  and  Snower  (1986) 
and  Blanchard  and  Summers  (1988)  distinguish  between  "insiders,"  who 
are  employed  hence  decision-making,  and  "outsiders,"  who  are  unemployed 
hence  disenfranchised.   Facing  our  short-run  demand  (4)  the  decision- 
making insiders  can,  in  the  short  run,  have  a  higher  real  wage  rate  by 


accepting  less  employment.   Let  them  accept  the  fraction  X  employed  of 
available  labor  force,  where  0  <  X  <_  1.   In  other  words,  if  L  >  XF 
insiders  will  insist  on  a  higher  real  wage  rate.   If 

L  =  XF  (5) 

they  will  be  happy  with  the  existing  real  wage  rate.   If  L  <  XF  they 
will  settle  for  a  lower  real  wage  rate. 

Consider  the  fraction  X  a  parameter,  then  (5)  will  be  a  solution 
for  employment  corresponding  to  Friedman's  (1968:  8)  "natural"  rate 
1  -  X  of  unemployment.  The  fraction  X  would  reflect  institutional 
dimensions  of  the  labor  market  such  as  union  density.  Cross-country 
measurement  of  movements  in  employment  and  union  densities  is  repro- 
duced in  Appendix  I  and  found  to  be  in  good  accordance  with  our  inter- 
pretation of  labor  supply  (5). 

7 .   The  Wage-Employment  Tradeoff 

The  real  wage  rate  insiders  will  be  happy  with,  given  their  natural 
rate  X  of  employment,  is  found  by  inserting  (5)  into  (3): 


-7- 


w 

-  =  aa(XF)"0S6  (6) 


What  is  the  implied  slope  of  the  Phillips  curve?   As  long  as  the 
ratio  w/P  satisfies  (6)  the  levels  of  the  money  wage  rate  w  and  price 
P  can  be  anything:   the  Phillips  curve  is  vertical.   Where  labor  can- 
not negotiate  real  but  only  money  wage  rates,  short  contract  periods 
will  have  to  do,  and  a  temporarily  finite  slope  of  the  Phillips  curve 
is  possible  until  successive  rounds  of  collective  bargaining  have 
restored  levels  of  the  money  wage  rate  w  and  price  P  satisfying  our 
wage-employment  tradeoff  (6).   Cross-country  measurement  of  movements 
in  employment  and  real  wage  rates  is  reproduced  in  Appendix  II  and 
found  to  be  in  good  accordance  with  our  wage-employment  tradeoff  (6). 

8.   Physical  Output 

Write  the  firm  production  function  (2)  as 


L  a 
X  =  a(-)  S  (7) 

S 


-8- 


and  the  firm  demand  for  labor  (4)  as  the  factor  proportion 


T  -1/6 

L         l/fi  W 

-  =  (aa)1/0(-)  (4) 

S  P 


Insert  (4)  into  (7),  then  on  the  right-hand  side  of  (7)  everything 
except  S  is  common  to  all  firms.   Factor  out  all  such  common  factors 
and  sura  (7)  over  firms.   Then  S  becomes  aggregate  physical  capital 
stock,  and  X  aggregate  physical  output.   We  already  know  that  the  fac- 
tor proportion  (4)  holds  for  the  firm  as  well  as  for  the  economy  at 
large.   Read  it  for  the  economy  at  large,  multiply  out  in  (7),  and 
arrive  at  a  production  function  of  the  form  (2)  now  holding  for  the 
economy  at  large.   Into  such  an  aggregated  (2)  insert  (5)  and  write 
physical  output: 

X  =  a(XF)aSB  (8) 

9.   Desired  Capital  Stock  and  Investment 

Desired  capital  stock  and  investment  are  long-run  commitments  to 
be  determined  by  maximization  of  present  net  worth.   Here  the  firm  can 


-9- 

no  longer  consider  Its  physical  capital  stock.  S  a  constant  or  ignore 
the  effect  of  investment  1  upon  it. 

We  begin  by  defining  the  rate  of  growth  of  a  variable  v  as  the 
derivative  of  its  logarithm  with  respect  to  time: 


dlog  v 

gv  -z  e-  (9) 

dt 


To  find  the  capital  stock  desired  by  the  firm  define  physical 
marginal  productivity  of  capital  stock  as 


3X  X 

<  =  —  =  aBLaSB     =  6  -  (10) 

3S  S 


Firms  were  purely  competitive;  then  price  P  of  output  is  beyond 
their  control.   At  time  t,  then,  marginal  value  productivity  of  capi- 
tal stock  is  <(t)P(t). 

Let  there  be  a  market  in  which  money  may  be  placed  or  borrowed  at 
the  stationary  nominal  rate  of  interest  r.   Let  that  rate  be  applied 
when  discounting  future  cash  flows.   As  seem  from  the  present  time  x, 


-10- 

then,  marginal  value  productivity  of  capital  stock,  is  <(t)P(t)e 
Define  present  gross  worth  of  another  physical  unit  of  capital  stock 
as  the  present  worth  of  all  future  marginal  value  productivities  over 
its  entire  useful  life: 


k(-r)  e  /  <(t)P(t)e  r(t    T)dt 


Let  firms  expect  physical  marginal  productivity  of  capital  stock 
to  be  growing  at  the  stationary  rate  g  : 


g  (t  -  t) 
<( t)  =  <(r)e  < 


and  price  of  output  to  be  growing  at  the  stationary  rate  g 


e  ( t  -  t) 
P(t)  =  P(r)egP 


Insert  these,  define 


p  =  r  -  (gK  +  gp)  (11) 


-11- 


and  write  Che  integral  as 


<(x)  =  /  <(T)P(x)e  p(t    T)dt 


Neither  <(t)  nor  P(t)  is  a  function  of  t  hence  may  be  taken  out- 
side the  integral  sign.   Our  g  ,  g  ,  and  r  were  all  said  to  be  sta- 
tionary; hence  the  coefficient  p  of  t  is  stationary,  too.   Assume 
p  >  0.   As  a  result  find  the  integral  to  be 


k  =  <P/p 

Find  present  net  worth  of  another  physical  unit  of  capital  stock 
as  its  gross  worth  minus  its  price: 

n  =  k  -  P  =  (</p  -  1)P 

Capital  stock  desired  by  the  firm  is  the  size  of  stock  at  which 
the  present  net  worth  of  another  physical  unit  of  capital  stock  would 
be  zero: 


<  =  P 


-12- 


Insert  (10)  and  find  capital  stock  desired  by  the  firm 


S  =  BX/p  (12) 


Define  investment  desired  by  the  firm 


I  =  gsS  =  BgsX/p  (13) 


What  is  g  ?   Let  it  be  correctly  foreseen  by  firms  that  because 
a  +  B  =  1  the  economy  at  large  will  have  the  solution  (20),  to  be 
found  presently,  and  let  that  solution  be  common  to  all  firms. 

What  is  p?   In  its  definition  (11)  let  it  be  correctly  foreseen  by 
firms  that  because  a  +  B  =  1  the  economy  at  large  will  have  the  solu- 
tion (23),  to  be  found  presently,  and  let  that  solution  be  common  to 
all  firms.   Historically  the  marginal  productivity  <  of  capital  has 
indeed  remained  stationary.   In  that  case  (11)  simply  collapses  into 
the  real  rate  of  interest,  common  to  all  firms. 

On  the  right-hand  sides  of  (12)  and  (13),  then,  everything  except 
X  is  common  to  all  firms.   Factor  out  all  such  common  factors  and  sum 
(12)  and  (13)  over  firms.   Then  X  becomes  aggregate  physical  output 
and  (12)  and  (13)  aggregate  desired  capital  stock,  and  investment, 
respectively. 


-13- 
10.   Consumption;  Equilibrium;  Money 

Let  the  aggregate  consumption  function  be 

C  =  cX  (14) 

where  0  <  c  <  1. 

Aggregate  equilibrium  requires  aggregate  supply  to  equal  aggregate 
demand: 

X  =  C  +  I  (15) 

To  determine  the  rate  of  inflation  we  must,  first,  define  the 
velocity  of  money  as  the  number  of  times  per  year  a  stock  of  money 
transacts  money  national  income: 

Y  =  MV  (16) 

and,  second,  consider  the  money  supply  M  and  its  velocity  V  to  be 
parameters  growing  at  the  rates  g^  and  g  ,  respectively. 


-14- 


II.   SOLUTIONS 


1.   Convergence 

The  key  to  our  solutions  for  growth  rates  and  levels  Is  Solow's 
(1956)  convergence  proof.   We  apply  it  as  follows.   Differentiate 
aggregate  physical  output  (8)  with  respect  to  time,  consider  our 
natural  rate  X  of  employment  a  stationary  parameter,  and  find 

gX  =  ga  +  agF  +  e«S  (17) 

Insert  (14)  and  the  definitional  part  of  (13)  into  (15),  rearrange, 
and  write  the  rate  of  growth  of  physical  capital  stock  as 


gs  =  (1  -  c)X/S  (18) 


Differentiate  with  respect  to  time,  use  (17)  recalling  that 
a  +  8  =  1,  and  express  the  proportionate  rate  of  acceleration  of 
physical  capital  stock  as 


-15- 


ggS  =  gX_  gS  =  a(Sa/a+  gF  "  gS}  (19) 


In  (19)  there  are  three  possibilities:   if  gQ  >  g  /a  +  gP,  then 


S  '  sa' 


ggs  <  °*  If 


gS  =  ga/ot  +  gF  (20) 


then  g   =  0.   Finally,  if  gc  <  g  /a  +  g,,,  then  g  _  >  0.   Conse- 
gb  b     a       r  gb 

quently,  if  greater  than  (20)  g<,  is  falling;  if  equal  to  (20)  gg  is 
stationary;  and  if  less  than  (20)  g  is  rising.   Furthermore,  g_ 
cannot  alternate  around  (20),  for  differential  equations  trace  con- 
tinuous time  paths,  and  as  soon  as  a  g  -path  touched  (20)  it  would 
have  to  stay  there.   Finally,  g   cannot  converge  to  anything  else  than 
(20),  for  if  it  did,  by  letting  enough  time  elapse  we  could  make  the 
left-hand  side  of  (19)  smaller  than  any  arbitrarily  assignable  posi- 
tive constant  e,  however  small,  without  the  same  being  possible  for 
the  right-hand  side.   We  conclude  that  gq  must  either  equal  g_/a  +  gp 
from  the  outset  or,  if  it  does  not,  converge  to  that  value. 

Once  such  convergence  has  been  established  we  may  easily  find  the 
corresponding  values  of  other  growth  rates:   insert  (20)  into  (17), 
recall  that  a  +  Q   =    1,  and  find  the  long-run  growth  rate  of  physical 
output 


-16- 


gx  -  gs  (21) 


Differentiate  (6)  with  respect  to  time,  use  (20),  and  find  the 
long-run  growth  rate  of  the  real  wage  rate 


«w/P  ■  ga/a  (22) 


Differentiate  (10)  with  respect  to  time,  use  (21),  and  find  the 
long-run  growth  rate  of  the  physical  marginal  productivity  of  capital 
stock 


g<  =  0  (23) 


As  we  recall  from  the  definition  (11),  g  was  one  part  of  the 
definition  of  the  real  rate  of  interest.   To  solve  for  the  other  part, 
insert  (1)  into  (16),  differentiate  with  respect  to  time,  use  (21), 
and  find  the  long-run  rate  of  inflation 


gp  =  §M  +  gv  "  gs  (24) 


where  g   stands  for  the  solution  (20) 


-17- 

We  have  found  our  natural  rate  X  to  be  absent  from  all  our  long- 
run  growth  rates  (20)  through  (24).   But  might  it  be  present  in  the 
long-run  levels  at  which  our  variables  are  growing?   We  shall  see. 

2 .   Real  Rate  of  Interest 

To  solve  for  the  long-run  level  of  the  real  rate  of  interest 
insert  (13)  and  (14)  into  (15),  divide  any  nonzero  X  away,  and  find 


Bgq 

P  -  —  (25) 

1  -  c 


where  g  stands  for  our  solution  (20).  Our  solution  (25)  has  no  X  in 
it:  the  long-run  real  rate  of  interest  is  invariant  with  the  natural 
rate  X  of  employment.  Differentiating  our  solution  (25)  with  respect 
to  time,  we  find  it  to  be  stationary — as  we  assumed  in  Sec.  I,  9  above. 


-18- 
3 .   Physical  Capital  Stock 

To  solve  for  the  long-run  level  of  physical  capital  stock  insert 
(8)  and  (25)  into  (12)  and  find 


.      l/o 
1  -  c 

S  =  (a  )     XF  (26) 

gS 


where  g„  stands  for  our  solution  (20).   Our  solution  (26)  does  have  X 
in  it:   the  long-run  physical  capital  stock  is  in  direct  proportion  to 
the  natural  rate  X  of  employment.   Differentiating  our  solution  (26) 
with  respect  to  time,  we  find  it  growing  at  the  rate  (20),  invariant 
with  X — as  it  should. 

4.   The  Real  Wage  Rate 

To  solve  for  the  long-run  level  of  the  real  wage  rate  insert  (26) 
into  the  short-run  level  (6)  and  find 


-19- 

B/o 

-  =  aai/a  ( )  (27) 

P  2 


where  g   stands  for  our  solution  (20).   Our  solution  (27)  has  no  X  in 
it:   the  long-run  real  wage  rate  is  invariant  with  the  natural  rate  X 
of  employment.   Differentiating  our  solution  (27)  with  respect  to  time, 
we  find  it  growing  at  the  rate  (22),  invariant  with  X — as  it  should. 

5.   Physical  Output 

To  solve  for  the  long-run  level  of  physical  output  insert  (26) 
into  the  short-run  level  (8)  and  find 


. i        1  -  c  B/o 
X  =  a  '   ( )    XF  (28) 

gS 


where  g   stands  for  our  solution  (20).   Our  solution  (28)  does  have  X 
in  it:   the  long-run  physical  output  is  in  direct  proportion  to  the 
natural  rate  X  of  employment.   Differentiating  our  solution  (28)  with 
respect  to  time,  we  find  it  growing  at  the  rate  (21),  invariant  with 
X — as  it  should. 


-20- 


III.   CONCLUSION 


We  have  found  a  stark,  contrast  between  the  short-run  and  the  long- 
run  scope  for  wage  policy.   The  simple  mathematics  of  the  contrast  is 
this. 

In  our  real  wage  rate  (6)  neither  a,  a,  6,  nor  F  is  a  function  of 
the  natural  rate  X.   Physical  capital  stock  S  may  or  may  not  be.   In 
general  differentiate  the  natural  logarithm  of  (6)  with  respect  to  X 
and  find  the  elasticity  of  the  real  wage  rate  with  respect  to  the 
natural  rate  X  to  be 


31og  (w/P)  31og  S 

S =  -  8  +  6  —  (29) 

31ogeX  31ogeX 


In  the  short  run  physical  capital  stock  S  can  be  considered  a 
constant  depending  on  nothing: 


Slog  S 

—  =  0  (30) 

31og  X 


-21- 

Insert  (30)  into  (29)  and  find  the  latter  collapsing  into  -  8: 
labor  can  have  a  8  percent  higher  real  wage  rate  by  accepting  a  one 
percent  lower  natural  rate  X  of  employment. 

By  contrast,  in  the  long  run  physical  capital  stock.  S  cannot  be 
considered  a  constant  but  is  a  variable  to  be  solved  for.   When  we 
solved  for  it  we  found  (26)  whose  elasticity  with  respect  to  X  was 


31og  S 

—  =  1  (31) 

31ogeX 


Insert  (31)  into  (29)  and  now  find  the  latter  collapsing  into 
-8+8=0:   labor  can  have  a  no  higher  real  wage  rate  by  accepting  a 
lower  natural  rate  X  of  employment. 

In  plain  English  the  reason  for  the  stark  contrast  is  that  in  the 
long  run  the  levels  (26)  and  (28)  of  capital  stock  and  output  simply 
adjust  to  X  and  are  correspondingly  lower:   the  economy  is  impover- 
ished, accumulates  less  capital  stock  and  produces  less  output.   Labor 
does  not  benefit.   Nobody  benefits. 


-22- 


APPENDIX  I.   U.S. -EUROPEAN  DIFFERENCES  IN  EMPLOYMENT  AND  UNION  DENSITY 


Friedman  (1968:   9)  never  meant  his  natural  rate  to  be  "immutable 
and  unchangeable."   Indeed,  over  the  thirteen  years  1973-1986  Freeman 
(1988b:   294-295)  found  actual  employment  as  a  fraction  of  working-age 
population  declining  steadily  in  OECD-Europe  as  a  whole  but  largely 
rising  in  the  United  States. 

Among  the  institutional  dimensions  reflected  by  the  natural  rate 
Friedman  (1968:   9)  mentioned  union  density.   One  would  expect  the 
employment  fraction  and  union  density  to  be  moving  in  opposite  direc- 
tions.  Roughly  speaking,  so  they  did:   over  the  fifteen  years 
1970-1985  Freeman  (1988a:   69)  found  union  density  rising  sharply  in 
Denmark,  Finland,  and  Sweden;  rising  moderately  in  Australia,  Canada, 
France,  Germany,  Ireland,  Italy,  New  Zealand,  and  Switzerland;  rising 
slightly  in  Norway  and  the  United  Kingdom;  declining  slightly  in 
Austria  and  the  Netherlands;  declining  moderately  in  Japan  and  sharply 
in  the  United  States.   In  Sweden,  however,  the  employment  fraction  and 
union  density  moved  in  the  same  direction.   Allowing  for  Sweden,  Barro 
(1988:   36)  found  the  persistence  of  low  employment  to  go  with  high 
union  density  and  large  size  of  government  but  only  in  countries 
lacking  centralized  bargaining. 


-23- 


APPENDIX  II.   U.S. -EUROPEAN  DIFFERENCES  IN  WAGE-EMPLOYMENT  TRADEOFF  (6) 


Differentiating  our  wage-employment  tradeoff  (6)  with  respect  to 
time  would  suggest  increases  in  employment  and  the  real  wage  rate  to 
be  of  opposite  orders  of  magnitude,  and  so  they  were:   over  the 
twenty-five  years  1960-1985  Freeman  (1988b:   296-297)  indeed  found 
countries  in  most  of  OECD-Europe  to  have  larger  increases  in  their 
real  wage  rates  and  smaller  increases  in  their  employment  than  had  the 
United  States  and  Sweden.   The  pairing  of  the  United  States  and  Sweden 
was  also  noticed  by  Ergas  and  Shafer  (1987-1988). 

Economists  from  Keynes  (1936:   14)  to  Summers  (1988)  have  insisted 
that  relative  real  wages  do  matter.   Under  decentralized  bargaining, 
wage  restraint  by  an  individual  union  may  lower  its  relative  real 
wages.   Centralized  bargaining  removes  such  fears.   Sweden  with  her 
centralized  bargaining  and  very  high  union  density  did  show  more  wage 
restraint  than  countries  with  decentralized  bargaining — as  Freeman  and 
Ergas-Shafer  found. 


-24- 


REFERENCES 


Barro,  Robert  J.,  "The  Persistence  of  Unemployment , "  Amer.  Econ.  Rev. , 
May  1988,  78_,  32-37. 

Blanchard,  Oliver  J.,  and  Summers,  Lawrence  H.  ,  "Hysteresis  and  the 
European  Unemployment  Problem,"  in  Cross,  Rod  (ed.)  Unemployment , 
Hysteresis  and  the  Natural  Rate  Hypothesis,  Oxford:   Blackwell, 
1988. 

Ergas ,  Henry,  and  Shafer,  Jeffrey,  "Cutting  Unemployment  Through 
Labour-Market  Flexibility,"  The  OECD  Observer,  Dec.  1987-Jan. 
1988,  19-21. 

Freeman,  Richard  B.,  "Contraction  and  Expansion:   The  Divergence  of 
Private  Sector  and  Public  Sector  Unionism  in  the  United  States," 
Journal  of  Economic  Perspectives,  Spring  1988,  2_,  63-88. 

* ,  "Evaluating  the  European  View  that  the  United  States  Has 


No  Uneraployment  Problem,"  Amer.  Econ.  Rev.,  May  1988,  78,  294-299. 


-25- 

Friedman,  Milton,  "The  Role  of  Monetary  Policy,"  Amer.  Econ.  Rev. , 
March  1968,  _58_,  1-17. 

Keynes,  John  Maynard,  The  General  Theory  of  Employment,  Interest,  and 
Money,  London:   Macmillan,  1936. 

Lindbeck,  Assar,  and  Snower,  Dennis  J.,  "Wage  Setting,  Unemployment, 
and  Insider-Outsider  Relations,"  Amer.  Econ.  Rev. ,  May  1986,  76, 
235-239. 

Maddison,  Angus,  "Growth  and  Slowdown  in  Advanced  Capitalist  Economies 
Techniques  of  Quantitative  Assessment,"  J.  Econ.  Lit. ,  June  1987, 
25_,  649-698. 

Solow,  R.  M. ,  "A  Contribution  to  the  Theory  of  Economic  Growth," 
Quart.  J.  Econ.,  Feb.  1956,  7£,  65-94. 

Summers,  Lawrence  H. ,  "Relative  Wages,  Efficiency  Wages,  and  Keynesian 
Unemployment,"  Amer.  Econ.  Rev.,  May  1988,  78,  383-388. 


-26- 

Windmuller,  John  P.,  "Comparative  Study  of  Methods  and  Practices," 
Collective  Bargaining  in  Industrialised  Market  Economies,  Geneva 
I.  L.  0.,  1987,  3-158,  especially  p.  19. 


D/129A 


HECKMAN 

BINDERY  INC. 

JUN95 

iwvl  ro.Pfc^  N  MANCHESTER 
B°*"0  INDIANA  46962