DIVERSIFICATION OPPORTUNITIES AND EFFECTS OF ALTERNATIVE POLICIES ON COSTA RICAN COFFEE FARMS By JOHN LEWIS BIEBER A DISSERTATION PRESENTED TO THE GRADUATE COUNCIL OF THE UNIVERSITY OF FLORIDA IN PARTIAL FULFILLMENT OF THE REQUIREMENTS FOR THE DEGREE OF DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY UNIVERSITY OF FLORIDA 1970 3L4£ AQRI- CULTURAL tIBRARV iiiiiiii / , I .' ACKNOV/LEDGMENTS The author wishes to express his sincere appreciation to Or. W. W, McPherson, Chairman of the Supervisory Committee, for his guidance and supervision throughout all phases of this research and for his valuable suggestions and criticisms in preparing this manu- script. Thanks are also due Dr. C. E. Murphree, Dr. C. W, Fristce, Dr. K. C, Gibbs and Dr. L. H. Myers for revievjing the manuscript and offering assistance. The author also 'wishes to thank Dr. H. L. Fopenoe, Director of the University of Florida's Center for Tropica] Agr i cul ture ,for his assistance in obtaining funds for support of the project. The assistance of the University of Florida's Computing Center is recognized and appreciated. The author also vjishes to express thanks to Mr. D. W. Parvin for his aid in interpreting the computer manuals. Special tlianks are also due numei-ous people in Costa Rica v;ho graciously supplied information and insights necessary to the comple- tion of this v;ork. The Oflcina del Cafe under the direction of Sr. Alvaro Castro Jimenez supplied transportat i on > office facilities, and techriical assistance. The author depended heavily on the advice of Ing. Hugo Castro, inn, Rogel'c Acosta and !nq. Edwin Mann in the initial phases of the study. The cooperation of the E/tension Service, of the Costa X\ca Ministry of Ayricult.ire is also appreciated. AcknovJledgment and thanks are due the .;vjny people v/ho supplied input-output information. Additional assistance v.'as given by others including Carlos Arroyo, Hester Barres, Janes Ross, Russel Desrosiers, Oscar Benavides, Robert F. Voertman, J. Robert Hunter, and Ernesto Sanarrusia. Special thanks are also due Miss Linda DiDuonni and Mrs. Sandi Davis for typing the first draft and to Mrs. Lillian Incenlath for typing the final manuscript. I I I TABLE OF CONTENTS Page ACKNOWLEDGMENTS ii LIST OF TABLES vi INTRODUCTION 1 An Economic Background 1 The Importance of Coffee to Costa Rica 3 The Marketing Situation for Coffee 5 The Pros and Cons of Diversification 9 Approaches and Attitudes toward Diversification .... 12 The Problem and Objectives 17 SCOPE AND METHOD OF STUDY 20 Selection of Areas and Farms 20 Description of Farms Studied 22 Pa 1 mares-San Ramon . 22 Alajuela 26 Acosta 28 The Linear Programming Model 30 The Enterprises and Restraints ^I The Sources of the Budgets ....... ^8 Assumptions of the Model 55 RESULTS 57 Optimal Cropping Plans 57 Farm 1 ' . . . 57 Farm 2 , 58 Farm 3 53 Farm '4 , 59 Farm 5 60 Farm 6 oO Farm 7 61 Farm 8 , . . , 62 Farm 9 62 Farm 10 63 Farm 11 63 IV Page Farm 12 Sk Farm 13 65 Farm 1^+ 66 i-'arm 15 67 Farm 16 68 Policy Analysis 69 Education for Better Farm Management 69 Taxation or Price Reduction 75 Payments for Coffee Removal 81 Price Differentiation 87 Reduction of Credit 90 Movement of Labor 93 Extra Credit 98 Subsidies for Alternatives 101 Stability of Alternative Crops 103 Comparative Costs of Coffee Removal 110 SUMmRY AND CONCLUSIONS 13^+ Effects of Improved Resource Allocation 13'4 Effects of Taxes or Price Declines I36 Effects of Credit Reduction 137 Effects of Price Differentiation I38 Effects of Increased Credit 139 The Choices of Alternative Crops ]kO Comparative Costs of Coffee Removal 1 '+3 Potential Effects of Technological Advances in Coffee Production 1 '4^ The Qualifications of an Acceptable Alternative .... 1 't5 Diversification Versus Production Control ....... 1^6 GLOSSARY 1-^8 APPENDIX , 149 LITERATURE CITED I96 BIOGRAPHICAL SKETCH 202 LIST OF TABLES Table Page 1. Partial matrix of coffee selling activities ... 37 2. Comparisons between reported and optimal incomes and coffee output 71 3. The effects of improving coffee production technology on coffee production and income Jh h. Comparisons of optimal incomes and coffee outputs with traditional versus new enter- prises on farms in Alajuela and Acosta .... 76 5. Optimal coffee production with specified price declines per fanega of coffee 77 6. Optimal manzanas in coffee vjith specified price declines per fanega of coffee 79 7. Optimal net farm income v;i th specified pries declines per fanega of coffee 8O 8. Alternative crops increased first by declines in coffee prices 82 9. Coffee production vjith annual payments for coffee removal 83 10. Net farm income vjith annual payments for coffee removal 85 11. The alternative crops increased first by annual paymc^nts for coffee removal 88 12. Comparisons of income and coffee production •^ for differentiated prices versus single prices ...... 89 13. Optimal coffee production with various levels of reduced credit 5I 1 ^. Optimal net income with various le^-els of reduced credit 32 VI Table 15. 16. ■ 17. 18. 19. 20. 21. 22. 23. 25. 26. 27. 28. 29. 30. Optimal manzanas in coffee with various levels of reduced credit Marginal returns to credit with various levels of reduced credit Optimal family income with and without off- farm employment opportunities Optimal farm income and the reduction of permanent labor Effect of additional credit on income and coffee production Optimal farm outputs of various crops on Alajuela farms given base capital and credit constraints and extra credit equaling ij^OO and ^2,000 per manzana Optimal output of various crops on Acosta farms with high fruit prices given base capita] and credit and extra credit equaling (;i400 and i;2,000 per manzana The effect of a blackberry subsidy on optimal coffee output The effect of a strawberry subsidy on optimal coffee output Relationships betv;een long-term interest rates and manzanas planted to limes Lime prices and lime production Prices of oranges necessary to Initiate orange production on farms In Alajuela and Acosta Alternative methods of reducing coffee output on farm 1 Comparative costs of various metliods of coffee output reduction on farm 2 Alternative methods of reducing coffee output on farm 3 . , . Alternative methods of reducing coffee output on farm h ' . Page 95 96 97 99 00 102 104 ]0k 105 106 109 111 112 113 VI I Table 31. Comparative costs of various methods of reducing coffee output on farm 5 • . 32. Comparative costs of various methods of reducing coffee output on farm 6 . . 33. Comparative costs of various methods of reducing coffee output on farm 7 . . 3^. Comparative costs of various methods of reducing coffee output on farm 8 , . 35. The comparative costs of various methods of reducing coffee output on farm 9 . 36. The comparative costs of various methods of reducing coffee output on farm 10 37. The comparative costs of various methods of reducing coffee output on farm 11 38. The comparative costs of various methods of reducing coffee output on farm 12 39 The comparative costs of various methods of reducing coffee output on farm 13, given high fruit prices ^0, The comparative costs of various methods of reducing coffee output on farm ]U, given high fruit prices k] . The comparative costs of various methods of reducing coffee output on farm 15, given high fruit prices k2. The comparative costs of various methods of reducing coffee output on farm 16, given high fruit prices A-3. The comparative costs of various methods of reducing coffee output on fGrm 13, given low Truit prices kk. The comparative costs of various methods of reducing coffee output on farm 14, given low fruit prices . , '45. The comparative costs of various methods of reducing coffee output on farm 15, given low fruit prices Page 115 116 117 118 120 121 122 123 125 126 127 128 129 130 131 VI I I Table The comparative costs of various methods of reducing coffee output on farm 16, given ]ovj fruit prices Page 32 I X NTRODUCTION An Economic Background Costa Rica Is a small country in Central America vn th a popula- tion of 1.6 million people living on an area of 19,700 square miles (46, p. 11). The economy is dominated by agriculture which employed over 56 percent of the active vjork force in 1363 (45, p. 13). In addition, agricultural products accounted for approximately 30 per- cent of the gross national product in I966 and about 80 percent of the value of Costa Rica's exports (17, P. 3). Alleger described Costa Rica as a nation of small farmers (3, p. 33). This character- ization does not mean that land is evenly distributed among the pop- ulation, since farms of over 100 manzanas represent only 10.5 percent of all Farms and cover 70 percent of the total farmland area (23, p. 46). Nevertheless, the land distribution figures must be inter- preted with a realization that many large farms are in remote areas and that, except for sugarcane and bananas, the Intensively grown crops are do.^iinated by small end mldd!e~si 5:ed farms. In recent years, Costa Rica enjoyed the highest per capita in- come in Central America. The estimated grcis natioml product per person in I565 vjas ^'il5 compared to up. 3vBi-3(^'3 cf $303 for all of Central America (55, p. 3). In recent years Costa Rica has had a balance oF paymencs iM'oblein. Foreign debts iiave had to be continually rcnecotl atcd. From 1350 to 2 1967 the value of exports of coffee, bananas, cocao, cotton, beef, and sugar increased from 532,1 to 702,8 million colones (56, p, 3^+) . While the value of exports has increased despite unfavorable price trends, the value of imports has increased at a much faster rate. The value of exports exceeded the value of imports by 2^,3 percent in 1967 and by 12,2 percent in I968 ( 2^+) . Production of the basic food crops has exhibited erratic growth since 1950. Corn imports exceeded exports in 1951, 195^, 1956, 1959, 196^+ and 1966. Per capita consumption of corn in I966 was below the 1950 level (56, p, ^+2) , Rice production has almost tripled since 1950, with a stronger upward trend occurring after I958. V/hile the change is largely due to an Increased acreage, the average yields have increased since 1955 (56, p. 5). Per capita consumption of rice has increased. Bean production has also increased significantly, doubling the 1350 output in 1967- However, net imports of beans occurred in 1951, 1956, 1957, 1953, 1961, 1962 and 196^+, Per capita consumption has Increased 25 percent since 1950 (56, p. 28), The Costa RIcan population increased from 1,028,175 in 1955 to i,6U8,8l5 in i960 (15, p. 2), an annual average increase of more than k percent. While population grov.'th increases the demand for food, this demand Is also increased by a rise in per capita incomes. If food output is CO keep pace with the demands of both population and income grovjth, further changes In inputs and technology 'will be re- quired (13). The allocation of scarce foreign exchange to food imports limits the ability of a developing nation to purchase capita] goods needed for economic growth (U8, p, 5). A.TOther problem facing Costa Ricau planners is public finances. The costs of governmental services are increasing. Education is an example (55, p. 33). Schools are being expanded but more and more children crowd tiiem. With over 35 percent of the population under ten years old, education is costly (!9, p. kj) . Rapid population growth slows occupational changes (1). Thus while the Costa Rican economy has given the nation the highest per capita income in Central America and supports the most advanced social and educational programs in the region, it faces demanding requirements if it is to continue to grow. The Importance of Coffee to Costa Rica Coffee is Costa Rica's leading agricultural commodity, the chief export crop, and a major user of agricultural credit and labor. Coffee has historically accounted for 17 to 26 percent of the value of agricultural output (5^, p. 37). Despite a long history of pro- duction, coffee output has increased markedly in recent years. From 1955 to 1963 coffee output v.'ss doubled. Yields increased 27 percent while acreage increased over 58 percent (53, p. 10). Considerable effort was put into research and extension work which empiiasized tiie use of modern inputs in coffee production. Higher coffee prices in the 195Q's encouraged the expansion of coffee onto nevi lands. The modernization of coffee production is indicated by the fact that in 1963 , 27 percent of the farms reported fertilizer use on 53 percent of the land planted to coffee (23, p. 176). Fertilizer responses gave 13 to 233 percent increases in coffee yields in trials running from 1952 to I957 (69, p. 60), Since I963. production increases in- dicate an even larger use of off- farm inputs. In I967, coffee output k vias more than three times the average output in the 19^8 to 1952 period (29, p. 63). Thus coffee production has led in a change from traditional tovvard modern farming methods. Coffee is the major source of foreign exchange for Costa Rica. It accounted for 38.9 percent of total value of exports in I966, 41.2 percent in I965 and 42.2 percent in 1964 (15, p. I3). Thirty percent of the economically active population is associated v..'i th the coffee industry (54, p. 37), This underestimates coffee's importance as a source of wage earnings since many children harvest coffee and are not considered part of the economically active population. The harvest season usually coincides with school vacations. Also, earn- ings from coffee picking greatly exceed other farm labor earnings. Another benefit that comes from coffee production is soil con- servation, A v/el i-cared-for coffee planting protects the soil from driving rain and contour ridges that slow runoff are permanent and reinforced with v-joody root systems. Much of the land utilized by coffee is unsuitable for annual cropping unless very elaborate ter- racing is used (67). Lastly, coffee is a source of tax revenue. Taxes of $0,4-5 per quintal of exported coffee, ^2,00 per quintal of coffee consumed internally, and i;i0,20 per fanega of coffee fruit processed at the beneficios support the operations of the Oficina del Cafe, In addi- tion, an advalorum tax contributes to the national treasury. This advalorum tax is graduated in the folio. (ing manner: 10 percent if the average price exceeds $42,50 per quintal, ']\ pei-cent if the average price falls betv/een $40,G0 and $42.50 per quintal, 5 percent if the average price falls betv/een $37.50 and $40.00 per quintal, and 2-2" percent if Llie .average price fall^ between $35-00 and $37-50 per 5 quintal. No advalorum tax is paid if the price falls below $35-00 per quintal (Sk, p. 56). Declines in coffee prices are burdensome to governments which depend upon coffee earnings for foreign exchange and tax revenue (30, p. 15). This is particularly true in Costa Rica where a ]k percent decline in price resulted in a 57 percent loss in tax revenue per quintal and a 3 percent decline in price resulted in a 53 percent loss in tax revenue per quintal in the marketing years from I965-66 to 1966-67 to 1967-68, The price decline from I566 to I9S8 brought about a drop in tax revenue estimated at 2k million colones (55, p. 10). The Marketing Situation for Coffee Historically, coffee production has gone through highly cyclical price periods. Prices fluctuated in a cyclical pattern accentuated by periodic unplanned changes in supply caused by unfavorable weather conditions in Brazil (32, p. ^5^+) . When drought and frost cut Brazil's output the price would rise. This high price encouraged renovation of old coffee orchards and the planting of new ones. Later, when recovery of damaged groves occurred, output surpassed the earlier level. Prices then were pushed to new lows causing abandonment or neglect of coffee farms until unfavorable weather again stimulated high prices. Over the years, there have been short periods of shortage and high prices follov.'C-d by long periods of sur- plus and lovj prices (59, p. 8). These drastic price fluctuations stimulated coffee producers to seek remedial schemes. The first of these was a Brazilian lav; blccl;ing new plantings in I90?.. Political ly unpopular, this lav; was repealed and followad by valorization schemes with which large quantities of coffee were purchased and held off the market (32, p. kSS) . Brazil borrowed from British banks to make coffee purchases in I906, 1917, 1921 and 1927. Larger and larger crops were encouraged which became more and more difficult to store. Brazil burned over 78 million bags of surplus coffee from 1931 to 19^^ (73, p. ^23). Coffee production in other Latin American countries expanded in response to Brazil's price supporting activities. Grov-jth elsewhere caused Brazil to market a smaller percentage of the world coffee (73, p. his). international agreement to control coffee output was first attempted in Bogata in 1936. Later, the Inter-American Coffee Agreement was signed by 1^ producing countries and the United States. Selling quotas vje re established and the agreement lasted from 19^+1 to 19^3 (73, p. ^23). In 1957, coffee producing nations agreed upon a voluntary system of export regulation. This agreement failed to check the dovjnv;ard price movement (59, p. 13). Finally, the inter- national Coffee Agreement received the support of k^ producing and consuming countries in I9S3. By chance, a severe frost cut the Brazilian output that year and, as a result, quotas were increased to give help to the coffee consumers as prices rose (59, p. 1^). The demand for coffee is believed to be inelastic with respect to price. !f this is true, a free-market solurion would result in lovjer gross income to producers than would occur if output were limited by some kind of a cartel arrangement. EconomisLs generally view trade agree- ments vji th a skeptic eye. Both experience and theory show that, v;i th price maintenance at or above a free-trade level, pressures and temp- tations arise to break or by-pass the agreement since high prices tend to encourage more production (37, p. 108). Nevertheless, the International Coffee Agreement has reduced price fluctuations and is considered to be effective enough to justify extension for five more years from 1968 (8, p. 188). However, the reduction in world output from I965-66 to 1966-67 occurred mostly in Brazil where weather has historically caused wide production varia- tion. The 1963 Agreement was concerned with regulating sales and made no attempt to regulate production, in 1968, a new article was written Into the International Coffee Agreement setting up the Diversification Fund (3^). This change provides for compulsory payments (U, S. $0,60 per bag in excess of 100,000 bags) into the Fund. This acts as a tax on coffee. Extra incentive is given to coffee producing nations to devise crop diver- sification projects. Eighty percent of the compulsory payments can be used within the producing country on approved projects. If not used domestically, the unused payment must be paid to the Fund in freely convertible currency. Thus each country will be motivated to develop local diversification projects by the desire to conserve scarce foreign exchange. Producing countries have used different programis to check coffee output. As mentioned earljer, Brazil first attempted to control out- put in 1902 vi'\ th a law prohibiting new plantings. More recently pay- ments have been made fc coffee removal (bO), Participation in the program, has bean vol untary ,vji th 6'l8 mi II loo coffee trees pulled out from June, 1S62 to December, I965. Plans had called for the removal 8 of two billion trees and part of the lack of response was blanjed on inflation which lowered the value of the fixed payments from $0.0A- to $0,01 per tree. The effect on coffee output was small. The program included no restriction on planting. In Colombia, Inter- national Development Bank (IDB) loans have been used to further credit, infrastructure, education, commercialization and industrializa- tion of alternative products. In Mexico, rubber, citrus and avocado plantings are being promoted in a program directed at the small coffee producer (27), In El Salvador, sugar, corn and rice produc- tion has been expanded. Modern corn and rice production gave returns reported to range between $3.00 and $7-50 per $1.00 spent on new in- puts. Nevertheless, the expansion of cereals was accompanied by a reduction in cotton and beans, rather than coffee (7'+). In Guatemala, pilot tests of tea, citrus, dairy and oil palm have been initiated. Over $1.9 million in foreign money has been invested in the program. Total costs surpassed $5.8 million invested on 282 farms covering 3,900 hectares (6). Guatemala also is developing a rubber industry. In 1965, rubber was planted on 26,000 acres. Projections estimate gross returns of $2'+ million from 80,000 acres (75). In Costa Rica, credit for new coffee plantings has been restrict- ed. In addition, the Universidad de Costa Rica, the U, S. AID Mission, the University of Florida, and the Centro para la Promocion de Kxportaciones and Inversiones cooperated in a series of observation trials in six locations scattered throughout the western part of the coffee growing region. The municipality of Tui'rialba has initiated a regional diversification program wi th the Instituto I nterameri cano de Ciencas Agricolas. Financial support from tlie Oficina del Cafe and the Agency for International Development (AID), plus technical assistance from the instituto 1 nterameri cano de Ciencas Agricolas, the Peace Corps, and the Ministerio de Agr i cul tura .makes this a truly cooperative venture. The emphasis is primarily on research with a rapid follow-up of pilot commercial plantings. The project began with basic studies of fast growing trees, Tilapia fish ponds, and macadamia nut production. The stated main purpose of the project was to institutionalize an attitude of dynamic change (9). While it is still too early to evaluate results, leaders in another municipal- ity have talked of imitating Turrialba with a diversification project of thei r own. In summary, a review of the literature on Latin Am.erican coffee diversification shovjed more discussion and hypothesizing than prac- tical resul ts. The Pros __and Cons of Divers i fi cat ion There has been much discussion of diversification in recent years as a method to foster economic development. In a comprehensive study, Dalrymple (22) has compared monoculture and diversification. The advantages of monoculture include the follov;ing: 1. In some cases the monoculture crop has a clear comparative advantage both at dom.estic and international levels. The financial gap between the monoculture crop and next best alternative has been found to be too v;ide to nrirmit ratic^dl rlianje. 2. It may be easier to raise yields to give higher returns from on established crop thnr, to press for ":ore complex cropping systems. The short-run returr.s "o increased cpeci a 1 i zat ion v.'i th eccncnies of 10 scale iTiay be quite high. Th.e new knowledge arid skills required to improve production of an existing crop may be easier to learn than the technical requirements of a totally new crop. 3. Monoculture is generally focused on export crops which provide a developing country with needed foreign exchange and an easily administered tax system. h. Certain crops have more prestige and social status than others. The disadvantages of monoculture bring out accompanying economic di ff icul ties: 1. Producers under monoculture are subject to high risk induced by technical change and insect and disease problems. This is often labeled "putting a lot of eggs in one basket." 2. Because many of the monoculture crops are perennials, a production lag may fo]lov\' a decision to increase output. By the time the crop comes into production considerable investment has already been made. Excessive reaction to favorable price situations may occur when tliis lag follows a major change in resource allocation, rleadjustmsnt of supply to face a lowered price will be sluggish even in the face of losses since marginal costs may be easily covered. 3. The low price elasticity of demand for coffee results in sharp, snort-term price f 1 uctu-it ions caused by weather and biolocjical factors. The resulting high prices in the short run may trigger ir- reversible i nves tmoi-i ts . These investments plus technological advances can be expected to increase supply '..'hile demand is not likely to incease faster than population growth. As a result, prices are exoected to vjeaken over time. n k. Trade agreements limit sales to key markets and therefore increase both price and gross returns for the conimodity with an inelastic demand. Unless each producing country takes actions to correct the internal distortions of high incentives for the commodity covered by trade agreements, an imbalance encouraging overproduction of that commodity will result (53, P. 9). The advantages and disadvantages of diversification are roughly the inverse of those of monoculture. Diversification may be advanta- geous if It more fully utilizes labor and reduces econoinic risk {hS, p. 2k). A number of different sources of i ncomie gives protection against severe loss caused by insects, disease or bad weather condi- tions \-;hich may affect one particular crop but not others. Labor requirements may be spaced in such a way that one crop uses labor when another has a slack v.'ork period. Shifting from an export crop to food crops can lead to improved -utritional levels, especially if more fruits and vegetables are introduced Into the diet. Also, import substitution may save scarce foreign exchar.ge (22, p, 27). On the other hand diversification faces certain 1 i ini tat i ons. Research has been focused on a few major expert crops (22, p. 39). V/ithout much experience or local scr^r'.ific investigation to support a new enterprise, the innovating producer faces higher uncertainties with respect t.? the crop respor.'ia to .jn '"avorrb ' e fdctois and condi- tions ('hi, p. 1), The market for the alternative crop may not be sufficient to abiorb exparniing pi-oduction at profitable prices (22, p. k]) . Ev'ir, if a potential demand exists, the marketing facilities hiay not be adeo^ia te to move the nev^ output to consumers. The econ- omies of scale may res'jlt in poot^ effici'='ncy as a g-eater number of crops are produced and volume of som.e crops is reduced. This is 12 particularly a hazard for a nev/ crop introduced without sufficient volume to utilize efficient processing machinery. in cases where the established crop is a perennial, a high per- centage of the costs are fixed. Therefore, replacement by an alter- native requires that total costs, since all costs are variable, be considered in comparison with the variable costs in the case of the established crop. Also, costs associated with removing the old crop must be added into the cost of establishing the new enterprise. Another problem arises if a new crop uses either more or less labor than the established crop (22, p. 38). If the labor require- ment is much higher, labor scarcity may prevent adequate handling of the new crop. If much less labor is used, unemployment has social ramifications that may be prejudicial to the establishment of a new industry. The quantity of research, extension work and information services will have to be expanded if changes require wora complex agricultural systCirs (^8, p. 2h) . Diversification projects are likely to fail on farms where administration and managemant inadequacies greatly limit the returns to coffee because the new enterpi'ises are likely to be even more difficult Lo manage (27). Aoproaches and Attitudes toward Diversification Crop diversification is defined as a movement av/ay from mono- culture wi tri the gi"ov.'Ing of new or additional crops (22. p. i). 'tore detailed descriptions may be conflicting ai'd the v-^valuatlon of diver- sification as a policy measure depends greatly upon just vjhat meaning is used. A [i;Q3t restrictive definition, anJ o:^e often thought of, Is the transfer of land from rr.cnocu 1 ture to alternative uses. However, 13 other resources besides land may be shifted from one use to another. Thus, diversification occurs if operating capital or labor is put to alternative use. For instance if labor or fertilizer is applied to stravv/berr i es rather than to coffee, diversification occurs. Diver- sification may even occur without a shift in resources or a reduction in primary crop output. This is possible if unused resources are associated with monocultural production. Therefore, if a farm were to begin to grow a crop of dasheen on swamipy ground formerly unused, using surplus family labor and operating capital, this would be an example of diversification. Thus for the purposes of this study, diversification is defined as a positive action which reduces the re let i ve importance of the primary crop. Crop diversification may occur at either the farm level or the national level. A recent advisory group proposed that Costa Rica should concentrate diversification efforts on areas un!^uited for coffee, where mechanization was feasible (63, p. 3). The program in this case would be to expand output using resources not now used to grow coffee. Crop diversification may either expand domestically consumed crops or promote new export crops. Although import substitution is reccgnived as beneficial, pi ani-;'"::rs seek to increase earnings of foreign exchange with new exports. The export deif..^rrd for a product facing a small country is often highly price elastic (57, p. 1), Thus, gener- ally the nev^ export crop has an advantaae over do-iestic crops in that price will remr.in more stable as output is expanded. The small size of che domestic market is couplc-c with a shortage of capital funds and modern knovj-how to limit diversi-^ied economic potentii^l (16, p. 33). 14 Furthermore, overproduction of basic food crops rr.ay result in govern- ment losses if high support prices are coupled with export subsidies (61). Others suggest that domestic crops offer better diversification possibilities because benefits of technological change are passed on to tlie consuming countries (66, p, ^32). Since a particular good from one country has perfect or close substitutes produced in other coun- tries, the demand curve facing each country is elastic. Hov-ever, the common agricultural export crops are inelastic when the entire world market is considered since they do not liave close substitutes, do not have many uses, and do not take a large share of the consumer's in- come {hk, p. ^+1). After a technological change is widely adopted, the result of increased output is often lovjer gross revenue. In this situation, the consumer benefits from lower prices and a higher real i ncome. The innovator may initially supply the domestic market when low early yields are compensated by high prices. Later, costs may be reduced to permit export or industrial use at much lov/or piMces. In addition, the scale of operations needed for new export ventures exceeds the capacity of existing producing units and marketing facil- ities (17, p. 12). The developm.ent of a new export d'op requires efficiency IF it is to meet the estabi'shed competition. Another area of debate centers around the question of who should diversify. Tvjo nearly opposite views have developed: an efficiency criterion of m.argi na 1 i ty proposes to rcc/.ive the low profit pioducers. In opposition, a criterion of welfare seeks the removal of those least hurt by shifting to alternative production. The removal of marginal producers is deemed desirable by both the Oficina del Cafe in Costa Rica and the Asociacion National del Cafe in Guatemala (5^+, p. 32; 27). Fernandez (27) defined marginal farms as those where costs exceed returns and also small farms where returns are low. One may note that this approach avoids antagonizing the politically influential in Guatemala as marginal farms are "liberated" for other uses. In Costa Rica, selective credit restric- tions were used to limit the expansion of coffee, particularly into areas producing low quality-low yield crops. The Oficina del Cafe favors this policy because it helps to maintain a higher average of quality as well as to restrain production. Newman (53, p. 1^) has criticized the marginal producer definition for being concerned with absolute rather than comparative advantages. Small farms are unsui ted for such alternatives as dairying and fruit production because ciiey cannot take advantage of economies of scale open to large operators. Small farms also lack reserve capital or credit availability to enable them to invest in the more productive alternatives. They are less able to v/ithstand possible loss of a new venture. The opportunity cost associated with removing coffee includes interest charges on foregone income, which may be limiting for farms near the subsistence level of income v^hen perennial alternatives are cons idered. Welfare considerations cannot be quantified for interpersonal comparisons. However, value judgments need iiot be made if the level of alternative output is used to evaluate different policies of diver- sification. The problem tlien becomes the calculation of the net costs of removal of a quantity of coffee from production on different farms. 16 If the means of production control is alternative use of land, this may be stated algebraically as follows: C =P -C -V -t-C +C r c c a a s where and C = net cost of removing one fanega of coffee, P = price of coffee, c ^ C = cost of producing one fanega of coffee V = value of alternative product produced with resources made available as coffee is reduced by one fanega, C = cost associated with producing V^, a "^ -" a ' C = cost of removing trees producing one fanega of coffee. Thus, the comparative advantage in coffee production may differ from the absolute advantage where C = P - C . If coffee is purchased and ^ r c c destroyed, the cost is higher as C - P . A mere general formula can be stated for calculating the unit cost of coffee removal, C = I , - l„ Q, - Q2 wtie re C - net cost of coffee removal r i. = net i nccr.ie before change r I - net income after ch-inoe 2 ^ - ■ Q = coffee production before c'lange Q,„ - coffee production after change Ideally, diversification would seek to reduce coffee vyi Lhout re- ducing 'ncome. Hcwever, given a price siti'aticn which stimulate:? 17 excess use of resources in coffee production, a more practical policy would attempt to minimize the costs of controlling output. The Problem and Objectives Although coffee is Costa Rica's most important commodity, con- tinued dependence on that one crop is considered detrimental to prospects for economic grov;th. This harsh statement Is supported by a pol I t i ca 1 -economi c situation in which the sales of coffee to the high consumption markets is now limited by international agreement. Thus if substantial growth Is to be achieved, it must occur In some other segment of the national economy. Technological changes are occurring In coffee production. These changes enable coffee to be produced at lower unit costs as modern inputs are added to traditional land and labor. The result is to Increase yields, !f resources are not shifted away from coffee, this increases production. The problem then arises as to which resources should be shifted to what alternative uses. Also, what policy mea- sures will facilitate changes which are both efficacious and equitable? One may also ask, are Costa Rica's farmers functioning as profit naximizers? Theodore Schultz has claimed that in traditional agri- culture farmers are not only profit maximlzers but that they also are quite efficient profit maxirrlzsrs (62. p. 'ih) . Ibv'ever, most of the farms studied do not truly fie the derinitlon of traditional agricul- ture used by Schultz (63, p. 30). Cultural techniques ''or coffee have not remained unchanged for cenarat i ons and further changes are occurring (32, p. 432). Costa Rica's emphasis on primary education already has accomplished much toward the investmenr In human resources 18 necessary to change traditional attitudes (63, p. 201), Schultz has designated the human agent as the key variable in explaining differ- ences in agricultural productivity (63, p. 17). The existence of experimental farms, scattered research plots, extension agents and agricultural schools also takes Costa Rica out of the category of traditional agriculture. Costa Rica admittedly does have many traditional farmers. How- ever, the threat of overproduction of coffee does not come from that direction. Recent yield increases Indicate non- t radi t i onal behavior, while increased coffee acreage has been relatively unimportant (15, p. 21). Schultz describes a transitional classification of agriculture between the traditional and the modern (&3, F- 107). Vas t . dl sequi 1 i b- rium is said to exist with differences in marginal productivity and overuse or undsruse of factors. The expanding use of fertilizers and pest control chemicals (15, p. 7) indicates that transitional changes toward modernization are occurring In Cos'>;a Rica. Nevertheless evaluating the farm case studies with respect to expectations given by Schultz's theories may be 1 P; teres 1 1 ng. Tradi- tional farm situations could be expected to give marginal value products near or at current prices of resources. On the other hand, transitional farm situations may put extremely high values on certain resources. Linear proyramming solutions may be compared with actual farm operations to judge the efficiency of farm decision makers. This may be of particular interest in explaining the continuance of traditional methods with some crops while changes occur with others. Specifically che objectives of this study were to evaluate farm 19 income opportunities frorn producing coffee and from alternatives and to determine the effects that selected programs would have on coffee production, resource use and incomes. At the same time, comparisons can be made of current resource use and optimal resource use to test the hypothesis that the farmers are income maximizers and that tradi- tional economic behavior has economic motivations. In addition, the comparisons may be used to determine what changes or adjustments in farm operations would be profitable. SCOPE AND METHOD OF STUDY Selection of Areas and Farms Coffee is grown in Costa Rica under a wide range of climatic and ecological conditions. Three geographic areas were included in this analysis. The data vje re taken from a study carried cut under a University of Florida - AID Contract in Costa Rica, No. la-26l. Budgeted comparisons between coffee enterprises and leading alter- natives in 12 areas are given in An Economic Analysis of Coffee Pro- ducing Areas, Cosca Rica (11), Palmares-San Ramon, Alajuela and Acosta v.'ere the areas selected for this intensive study. This selection was based on the following cri teria: 1. Coffee and alternative crops should be found grovjing under similar ecological conditions. 2. Enough coffee should be produced to make changes inportant to national totals. 3. Different areas should I'epresent a wide range of coffee productivity and alternative choices. Some consideration was given to including the Turrialba area in this study, HowR'/er, the d i ver; i f i ca t i on project in that ;^rea was just beginning to gene'-ate completely new data when this work was undertaken. V/ithIn the three areas selected, the local extension agents 20 21 selected farms they regarded as typical of size and class categories common in each particular region. Data were collected by the agents listing the resources available and the resources used on each farm. A monthly breakdown of labor vjas supplied for each enterprise. In addition, budgets for several crops grown in the areas w'ere made available from the Banco Nacional de Costa Rica and the Banco de Credito Agricola de Cartago. The list of enterprises was further supplemented by crop cost study reports of the Hinisterio de Agri- cul tura. It is admitted that the farm case study appi-oach cannot be sta- tistically supported. However, by drawing upon the prior knowledge of the local agricultural scientists, costs could be held to a fraction of the costs of working with a large random sample. Because it is likely to be the better farmers who contact and work with the extension agents, op.e may expect that the "typical farms" of the extension agents may be aoove average. Nevertheless, this direction of bias need not be undesirable, since it is this group of farmers viho are most likely to first respond to economic incentives with either increased coffee output or diversification to alternative products. Furthermore, the farms selected are in no way expected to be averaged to give a quantitative measure of policy response for more than each farm itself. The genera 1 i zat i ons possible must be limited to direction and nature of cliange which may i r. turn lead to specula- tions concerning the response oF the toial coffee industry. Although quantitative analysis is made at the farm level, extrap- ol'^ition to larger area'i must be v.'i th descriptive or qualitative anal- 22 ysis. In this manner, associations can be made between poiicy re- sponses and various resource situations or enterprise possibilities. The uniformity, irregularity or lack of response can be noted for various policy alternatives. Thus the sample may indicate the kind of farm likely to support or oppose a particular political measure. Description of Farms Studied The farms selected for analysis are all located on the Pacific side of the Continental Divide. Farms were selected to represent the most common size-type categories found in the three areas. Fa] ma res- San Ramon This area is made up of the intensive coffee-growing districts of the cantons of the same names. The Canton of Palmares, except for the districts of Candelaria and Esquipulas, vjhich are not well suited for coffee, reported coffee on 9^ percent of the farms and 37 percent of the land in I963 (25). The soils are f 1 uvi o- 1 acus tr i ne groups containing diatomite (iO, p, 3), Internal drainage may be a problem on level areas, A distinct dry season extends from December into April and Good Hard Bean (2) type of coffee is grown at elevations between 900 and 1,200 meters. Practically no rain falls from December to February (6'f). in the districts of San l^idro and San P\anion of the canton of San Ramon the Good Hard Eenn typo of coffee is produced at elevations of 1,000 to 1,200 meters. In these districts, coffee utilizes 12 percent of the land aiiar;-nt farm resources and parametric changes, ore particuU^r technology v-'as net obviously superior to the others. Also, an averaging of inputs and yields is not particularly meaningful since distinctly diffcrer.t Lcchnologles related to differences in yields are known to exist. In the decision as to the number of processes for an enterprise the availability and the accuracy of the data v;ere taken into account. Activities vjere chosen to represent different intensities of the use of labor and operating capital as well as different levels of modernization. Activities found on the poorer farms were included in the better farms' alternatives. However, the activities requiring high levels of technical skills were blocked for the poorer farms in the initial solution and were considered only in special parametric procedures. The activities were coded from budget data supplied by the ex- tension agents and also from the budgets of the agricultural credit reports of the Banco Nacional de Costa Rica and the Banco oe Credito Agncola de Cartago and the Minlsterio de Agricultura y Ganadena. These sources supplied data concerning material Inputs, labor hours and timing of various v-jork operations and expected yields of selected enterpi'ises in particular ai'eas. In addition, activities were syn- thesized from foreign Input-output data vjhlch vjsre modified to anticipate Costa RIcan conditions by adapting iabcr requirements for particular work operations from currently grovjn crops. Research studies of the Univcrsidad de Costa Rica were used to supply data for certain horticultural -jctivities. Activities based en foreign or small research plot dita were entered with what v/as believed to be "conservative" yield estimates. The results of plot trial yields v.'e re estimated by using the lowest variety yield wliich was not si jni f i cant 1 y different (at a 5 percent level) from the highest variety yi'^d. One problem that crcse w.is the fitting of the labor requirements vjithin the moiitlily labor con;- tr a i n ts . In most cases the farm enter- prise reports placed the labor for each work operation within a given month; however, in a few instances the reports spread work over a two- or three-month period. Overlapping t i ~ie periods would have made the computations much more costly. Instead, two processes were sometimes used for timing the input use of labor, and the labor uses in other cases were arbitrarily placed in months so as not to compete with coffee harvesting. The use of operating capital and short-term credit was handled together to avoid antagonizing the cooperating farmers. The extension agents felt that loan information was personal and requested that this section be deleted from the original forms. Therefore, total short-term expenditures were used as the right-hand-side constraint for the operating capital and credit row for each farm, "^his assum.ed that the farmers were using as much bank credit as they could get. As a result, the credit situation is oversimplified in the model, but the complications of overborrovn ng for consumption or non-agricultural uses are thus avoided. These complications would be difficult to identify using intervievjs since some common practices are of question- able legality. For the Palmares and San Ramon areas, the programming matrix was made up of 81 rows and 9^ columns. The rov;s included 12 for monthly labor use, 12 for monthly land use, 12 for temporary monthly labor use, k for monthly family harvesting labor, 1 for operating capital and credit use, 3 for tobacco ccntracC; I for i nves tm.ent , 1 for fixed expenses transfer, ]k for product transfer, 3 foi' coffee land, 1 for coffee harvesting, ' for corn sl-iel!ing, 1 for land transfer, 1 limiting row for traditional coffee market, sales, 2 crop rotation requirement rows, 2 labor movement rovjs, 9 exchange rows for parametric changes, and 1 profit row. The columns included 10 coffee grovjing activities, 9 tobacco growing activities, 8 corn grov/ing activities, k joint corn and bean growing activities, k bean grovjing activities, 2 sesame growing activ- ities, 2 castorbean growing activities, 5 dairy activities, 2 beef activities, 1 peanut growing activity, 2 buckwheat growing activities, 1 chickpea grov;ing activity, 1 pigeon pea growing activity, 1 mixed crop producing activity, 1 annual to monthly land use transfer activ- ity, 3 coffee selling activities, 3 tobacco selling activities, 3 grain selling activities, 1 calf selling activity, 1 milk selling activity, k monthly labor selling activities, 2 yearly labor selling activities, 12 temporary labor hiring activities, 1 borrowing activ- ity, 1 coffee planting activity, 1 coffee-destroying activity and one fixed cost transfer column. A listing of the row entries of each of the activities programmied is given in the Appendix, Only farms 1 and 2 were programmed to allow the use of all the activities coded for the area. Farms 5, 6, 7 snd 8 were not using the same high level of technology as that found on farms I and 2. The two most productive coffee-growing activities were blocked by removing the coffee production transfer card. A change row entry was substituted and an investment entry added so that a parametric pro- cedure v^ould evaluate the acceptability of the change if education v;ere to permit its occurrence. Farms 3 ^nd k vje re below -average coffee producers. They wei'e permitted to use only the l.?ast profilahle cof Fee- g rowi ng activities of the area. Again a pa r.irr.'^ t r i c procedure allowed higher production. 45 assuming that education and long-term investment could make the higher yields poss ib le. In the Alajuela area, the matrix was composed of Sk rows arid 87 columns. The rows included 12 for monthly labor, 12 for monthly land, 12 for temporary labor, k for monthly family labor for coffee harvest- ing, 1 for investment, 1 for operating capital, 1 for coffee harvest, 19 for product transfers, k for rotation limits, 1 for yearly land, 1 for fixed expenditures, 3 for coffee land, 2 for off-farm labor movement supply, 1 for limiting sales in the traditional coffee market, 12 for changes in parametric modifications and 1 for profit. The colum.ns Included 9 coffee growing activities, 1 lime growing activity, 1 orsp.v^e growing activity, 3 corn grovjing activities, 2 corn-bean growing activities, 3 bean growing activities, 1 pineapple growing activity, 1 stra-wberry growing activity, 6 sugarcane growing activities, 3 cassava gro'-.'Ing activities, 2 cucumber growing activ- ities, 2 sweetpotato growing activities, 2 tomato grovjing activities, 2 svjeet pepper growing activities, 1 peanut grov.'ing activity, 1 chickpea growing activity, 1 buckwheat grovnng activity, 1 pigeon pea grov.'ing activity, 1 dairying activity, 3 coffee selling activities, 16 alternative product selling alternatives, 2 coffee harvesting activities, 2 all-year labor selling activities, k i;iOnthly labor selling activities; 12 monthly labor niring activities, 1 fixed cost transfer column, 1 land transfer column, 1 coffee planting activity, 1 coffee destroying activity, and 1 bcrowing activity for long-term credi t. With the exception of farm 9, f^'ie two highest-yielding coffee activities were blocked for tlie original solutions and allowed to A6 enter with parametric changes. Lime and strav;berry selling activities reflected prices estimated for processing use. These prices were (^13. 00 per quintal for limes and ijl.OO per pound for strawberries. These prices were conservative estimations for the Central American Common Market and v/ere programmed both upward and downv^ard to fit conditions of the fresh market and v^orld market, respectively. Actually, average current prices are much higher in the local fresh fruit markets; hov»jever, these high prices vjould be unstable in the face of any sizable change in quantity. Tomatoes and svveet peppers were also priced for processing use. The price used for sweet peppers was lower than the quoted contracting price because pepper contracts were tied to tomato contracts. Cassava, cucumbers, and svjee tpota toes were priced at the reported market lows of the tv;0 years prior to the survey. Parametric changes lowered vegetable prices to levels competitive in the world market. While substantial changes in technology would be required if the fruit and vegetable activities replaced coffee, these changes were permitted in the model because the extension and research facil- ities seem capable in the zone. The experim.ent station of the Universidad de Costa Rica is located in the zone and specializes in horticultural crops. It is easier to seil ,-;e\j idias when they have been tested under local conditions and tli.e results are being applied by the agronomists on their pi"ivate commercial farms. !n the study of the Acos ta area, the matrix contained 65 I'ows and bO columns. The rows included 12 for monthly labor, 12 for monthly tampor?-ry labor ?L'[:plv, ] <^or i .ives tment , I for operating capital, 3 coffee l--;nd lirriiting rcv;s , 5 for mcnthly family labor for hi harvesting, 1 fixed expenditure transfer row, 1 rev; limiting coffee sales to the traditional markets, 1 coffee harvesting row, 1 yearly land supply row, 9 for product transfers, 2 for off-farm labor move- ment and 1 profit row. The columns included 7 coffee growing activities, 2 joint coffee- orange growing activities, 3 joint corn-bean growing activities, 1 blackberry growing activity, 2 orange gro'wing activities, 2 beef producing activities, 5 dairy activities, 1 lime grov-jing activity, 3 coffee selling enterprises, 8 selling enterprises for other farm products, 2 coffee harvesting activities, 5 monthly labor sailing activities, 12 monthly labor hiring activities, 1 fixed cost transfer column, 2 yearly labor selling activities, 1 coffee planting activity, 1 coffee destroying activity, and I borrowing activity for long-term credit. Since the growing periods for all the crop activities programmed for Acosta overlapped, land was programmed as a single resource instead of being divided into monthly intervals of use. Ecologically, Acosta is poorly suited to annua! cropping. Corn and beans were included because they are traditionally grovvn. Other annuals were excluded from the area's model in order to conform v/ith conservation !"equ i 3 i t i es. The coffee yields in Acosta are less than the yields of the other tv.'O areas. Poorer t-ichnology may have resulted from relative isolation in past years. Hovjever, lov;er fertility is c'liefly responsible for lo'wer yields, Tv.'O higher-yielding coffc;e growing activities were blocked in the initial solution but were allo'wed to enter in a parametric procedm'e representing technological change. Two price levels were used for fruit selling in Acosta since selling opportunities could be greatly affected by the nearness to market outlets. Risks and transportation costs vyould be reduced if a processing plant v.'e re built in the area. Prices were discounted 30 percent for limes, 25 percent for oranges and 50 percent for black- berries when local outlets were not anticipated, in calculating production costs for the production activities, short-run interest charges of 8 percent were added to the costs of materials. The Sources of the Budgets !t was necessary to use agronomic data from several different sources to construct the matrix of input and output data used in the study. Farm resource information and input-output data were provided by the extension agents in each area analyzed. The extension agents collected data from the farms they considered typical of the various farm size and type classifications found In their particular region. Most of the budgets for coffee, corn, beans and sugarcane were provided by the cooperating exiension ?.gen1.5. Th=se vi^re supplemented by data provided by the Banco Nacional de Costa Rica (18) and the Banco de Credito Ag.-icola de Ci'-rtogo (58). San Ramon and Palmares farms were grouped together in the analysis, !ng, Efrain Abarca collected data From San Ramon including budgets used in the most productive coffee ectivities yielding 27.6, 25.7 •^nd 20.0 fanegas per manzana,, !ng. Danilo Zamora collected data from Palmares farms which reported coffee yields of 1'3.0, 15.0, snd 5.3 ^anegas per mianzana. The best yields included herbicide use, three application-: of fertilizers, insecticide use and moderate pruning and V/'eedirig labor, Coinnif)n piactices incli-'ded the use of k9 fertilizer and insecticides and gave yields above the national average. Coffee activities using traditional methods were programmed from data of the Banco Central de Costa Rica (7). Moderately heavy labor with few purchased Inputs produced a yield of 9.0 fanegas per manzana. An activity of semi -abandoned coffee was based upon conversations with Ing. Hugo Castro. Yields up to '4,0 fanegas per manzana were obtainable vji thout purchased inputs other than sacks and without labor except harvesting and enough weed cutting to allow the pickers to walk. The extension agents' fa^m budgets also included corn and bean activities. Common corn yields ranged from 13.3 to ^0,0 quintales per manzana. Higher-yielding activities v;ere programmed from data furnished by Ing, V/alter Villalobcs from k-S Club plots at Santa Ana. Yields \-;are modified to 70,0 quintales per manzana maximum to corre- spond with the reportedly poorer grovnng conditions. The m.oderate use of fertilizer and insecticide, as reported in the v;orkshee ts of the Banco Nacional, yields 48,0 quintales (13). Bean activities viere based on budgets from the follov.'ing sources. Modern technology yielded !8 and 20 quintales par manzana according to budgets derived from a ministry of agriculture publication (51). The Banco Nacional supplied budgets of low-yielding bean crops from broadcast planting that yielded only k.2 quiritales per manzana and traditional methods that yielded 9-6 quintales per manzana (18). Joint corn and bean production activities were programimed allow- ing combinations of the average and poorer yielding corn and bean activities commonly grov.n together. Tobacco grov/irig activities were progranim.ed from budgets of the Junta de DePensa del ToL;ico (36) and tl'ie Banco i-lacional (13). Yields 50 ranged from 18 to 20 quintales per manzana but the budgets from the Banco Nacional used 1 ov^ r levels of inputs. Sesame v;as programmed using a budget of traditional methods supplied in Ospino's work (58). A budget of modern practices for growing sesame were synthesized using data from the United States (21, 38, 39). An estimate of yield expectations was placed at 20 quintales per manzana despite reported yields up to 35 quintales per manzana. The castorbean production activities were ba^ed on synthesized budgets based upon foreign agronomic data (20, 72). Yields ware estimated at Jih quintales per manzana. The traditional activities for producing dairy were based upon reported budgets from Atenas by Ing. Adrian Prado, More intensive dairy production activities were based on budgets from Heredia supplied by Ing. Carlos Norza. Production ranged from ^00 to 1,200 bottles of milk per manzana with extensive land use and from 1,000 to 2,000 bottles with more intensive operations. An extensive beef calf producing activity and a moderately inten- sive beef producing activity were budgeted by Ing. Ramon Castro in San Carlos with one cow per 5-0 manzanas in the first case and one cow per 1.5 manzanas in the second, fluch higher range productivity was reported In studies made in Puerto Rico (1^). However, the cost of production v.ould not bo covered by Costa Rican prices. Pigeon pea producticn activities v;ere based on budgets synthesized from agronomic data cliiefly from Havya i i (3I, ^O) modified by Costa Rican recommendat i tii,5 (50). Reported yields reeched 20 quintales per manzana. Te les 51 Buckwheat was Included as a catch crop. Yields viere programmed at 8 and 20 quintales depending upon the time of planting. Reported production In Mexico (70) and Ceylon (k) showed that this crop could be grown in tropical countries. - ' A peanut production activity was included although part of th soils may not be well adapted. Yield vyas programmed at 20 quintal per manzana as Banco Naciona] data from Alajuela vjere used to synthe- size a budget. Chickpeas were Included as a dry season catch crop. Cultivation is similar to beans ('47) and the yield expectations are 5 quintales per manzana. A mixed crop enterprise v;as synthesized from other budgets combining corn and legumes with high labor Inputs. Coffee price was determined by an unweighted average of the prices paid by the beneficlos in Palmares in the I966-67 crop year. Corn and bean prices were reported by the extension agents. Peanut and sesame prices were included in the credit vjorksheets of the Banco Nacional (18), Castorbean price was computed from the world dol la- price. Buckwheat v;as priced arbitrarily low to reflect probably limited acceptance as a feed grain. The chickpea and pigeon pea prices reflected estimated v^jholesale prices based upon retail prices in S.-T'n Jose as coimpared v.'ith beans. In the study of the Alajuela farms, budget data on coffee produc- tion were supplied by Ing, Guiilermo Montenegro, Yields rar[ae'J from 25 fanegas per manzana on the best farm to 16 fanegas per manzana on the poorest farm. The maximum yield pernitted without technological change inodi f i '. at i ons v^as 20 fanegas per maiizana except on farm 9 which had already adopted modern production techtii ques. Traditional and 52 semi -abandoned coffee production activities vjere included with the same coefficients used in the Palmares-San Ramon matrix. Lime production vjas programmed with input-output data synthesized from Florida sourcas (kl) . Yields were ^00 quintales per manzana. This approximates a U. S, yield of kSl bushels per acre. Costs of establishment used U, S, costs but annual labor costs were modified by data from Costa Rican orange production budgets. The orange production activity was programmed from data of modern orange production in Guatemala (ks) and Florida (28), Yields vary with the age of the trees but an estimated yield of a mature grove was taken at 1 ,020 cien (hundred fruit). This approximates 300 boxes of fruit per acre. Tomato production activities covered common and modern producing techniques. The common yield of 11.25 tons per msnzana was reported in a budget worksheet of the Banco Nacional (18). Experimental results of agronomic trials show yields that surpass 20 tons per manzana (26). Corn production activities were based upon ^f-S Club budgets v.'hich reported yields of 90 quintales per manzana and upon extension agent reports of corn yielding 60 quintales per manzana. Corn produc- tion was also programmed in joint activities with beans where the output of 48 faregas and 20 fanegas of corn v.'as produced jointly with 18 and h fanegas of beans in budgets supplied bv jng. Guillermo Montenegro, Bean production was programmed with three distinct levels of technology. I'lod-srn inputs -/ielded 20 Quintales per manzana (Sl), broadcast beans yielded 5 quintales per manze-na and traditionally plante;.! hians yielded 10 q../) '•: ta 1 es per manzara (18). 53 The strawberry producing activity used Florida production data (12) modified by incomplete data from Alajuela and Heredia farms. Yields were procrammed at 250 quintales per manzana. This approxi- mates l'+,600 pounds per acre. Good California yields, for comparison, ranged from 48,000 to 60,000 pounds per acre (43) and Israel increased its average yields from 3,000 to 10,350 pounds per acre in six years (35). Sugarcane production activities were programmed from budgets supplied by the Banco Nacional (18) and the extension agency. Produc- tion ranged from 60 tons per manzana to ICO tons per manzana per harvest. In a period ranging from 38 to 48 months, three harvests v.'ere made. Production and inputs v.'ere totaled for the entire periods. Three cassava producing activities 'were programmed. Traditional methods were represented by a budget which yielded 150 quintales in a 21-i;'.opth grov;ing period (18). Intermediate yields were received b/ a budgeted production lasting two years (58). Higher yields, 275 quintales per manzana, vere Drograrnmed with more modern inputs and longer growing period of 26 r^onths (26). Total production per month increased with age but quality declined. Cucumber production activities represented different timing of modern techniauef b-'jsed up3n agronomic data furnished by the Alajuela experiment farm (52). Yields v.'ere 1 40 cuinteles per manzana. The svjeetpotato productlcn actlvlLy bes^d on modern inputs (5) yielded 200 quintales per manzana vjhicii tripled the yield of tradi- tional methods reported by the Banco Nacional (l8). A peanut" producing activ'tv utilized a budget reported by the Cartago bank (5S). Yieiui of 25 oul males per manzana were expected. Pigeon pea, buckwheat and chickpea production activities were included, based upon the same sources as used for the Pal mares-San Ramon study. Prices were based on an unweighted average for coffee, reported lows of vegetable prices, and estimates of potential industrial prices for tomatoes, peppers, strawberries and citrus. Since the projected horticultural marketing assumed much greater volume than current sales, price predictions viere lower than average prices but subject to considerable error. In the study of the four farms in Acosta, coffee production budgets vyere supplied by Ing. Rodrigo Cavallini of the San Ignacio Extension Agency. The better methods used fertilizer or other purchased inputs and yielded 10 fanegas par manzana which was con- sidered high for this region. Traditional methods yielded six fanegas and used small quantities of fertilizer and heavy labor in- puts. Coffee was grovjn with oranges and bananas on some farms v^ith poor yields of both coffie and fruit. Cofiee yitlaed five and six fanegas and oranges yielded 1,000 to 3.,000 fruit per nanzana on neglected trees. An activity used to program the possibilities of tecl-mol ooi ca I change was supplied by Edwin Mann of the Oficina del Cafe. Me budgeted production yielding lU fanegas per manzana in an adjoining district. An activity vjas also included representing semi -abandorrrent and yielding only two Fanegas per manz-Tna, A hi'jh yielding orange producing activity vjas included end based upon data taken from foreign sources (28, h^) . This activity yielded 102,000 orsnces ccr.ipared to 'j3,jG0 crangss per manzana prodijcv^d on a farm i n ■\co-s ta. 55 Corn and bean production vias reported with low to very low yields. Joint cropping produced 29, G.k and 16 fanegas of corn com- bined with 11, 9.6 and 6.6 fanegas of beans. The same beef and dairy production coefficients used in the Palmares study were included in the matrix. Lime production vias included with a yield of 400 quintales per manzana based upon Florida data (kl) . The inclusion of a blackberry producing activity also v/as based upon a composite of information from Florida (65) and Costa Rica. Yields of 16,000 pounds per manzana were anticipated. Assumptions of the Model There are certain assumptions and limitations of the model which should be clarified before the results are interpreted. Linear programming uses profit maximization vjithin a set of constraints as a single criterion for allocating resources. This v:ould deviate from actual practice especially in those cases vjhere the m.agnitude of gain is so slight as to not make a more complicated program worth the trouble when compared to a simpler, more easily managed plan of operations. Also, the model docs not take uncertainties and risks into account. Risks, that may be either real or imagined, enter into farm decision making. Yields and prices vary from year to year. The farm operator 'aM 1 1 actually be interested in fnaximizing profits only vjithin seme range of acceptable risk. The model forces all decisions to b3 made at once. Since it is a static model, grovjth possibilities ai-e not taken Into account. This is particularly troub]e<;ome In the case of short-term, credit and 56 operating capital restriction. Because of this feature, the model is conservative insofar as nev; resources are not permitted to be generated over time. All units are considered divisible. This does not cause a problem except in the case of cattle and labor movement. Theoreti- cally, part-time employment could explain fractional units of labor movement. RESULTS Optimal Cropping Plans in general, cropping patterns de te rmi ned with the initial linear programrning model did not greatly differ from the reported practices. With one exception, land was fully utilized during at least part of the year. Unused permanent labor was often available except during coffee harvest. The restrictions on hiring temporary day-vjage labor v.iere generally not constraining. Where horticultural crops vjere considered, operating capital v;as restrictive. This restriction occurred also on the smaller, poorer coffee farms. Marginal returns to short-term credit, calculated by using reported expenditures as a base, vjere either zero or well over the established interest rate. Parametric changes found coffee production to be stable in the face of moderate coffee price and yield decreases but responsive to technological Improvements and credit manipulations. Changes in the availability of credit, the interest rate, the labor supply, and product prices had a much greater effect on the alloca- tion of resources among the various alternative crops than they had on coFfce production. A brief suminary of optlm.al resource use will be given for each of the 16 farns. Farm I The optimal solution of this coffee- tobacco farm coincided with the reported prcducticn. Two manzcn-BS v,/sre planted to thinly spaced 57 58 corn and tobacco and three manzanas were used to produce coffee. In addition, two manzanas of buckwheat were planted in the dry season. The net returns (ijI9,78l) fell slightly below the farmer-estimated returns ((^22,500) because the model included extra labor costs and lower corn prices. Land and burley tobacco contracts were limiting rows with marginal values estimated at (;t^,069 and ^215, respectively. Temporary labor vjas hired in October and January. Permanent labor was fully utilized in May and October as well as from November through February v;here the model permitted coffee harvesting to exhaust the labor supply. A slight excess (?i8l) in operating capital occurred. Farm 2 The second farm from San Ramon was a small specialized coffee producer. The optinal solution for the linear programming model derived for this farm situation also produced only coffee. Net returns in the model were (pl8,02U ccmparad to (;il5,250 calculated from the farmer report. The model permitted the use of a higher- yielding coffee activity which proved slightly more profitable than the technology actually used. V/ith tobacco activities blocked, the only effective constraint vjas land. Permanent labor was exhausted only from November through February v^/hen coffee harvesting utilized all the labor. The farm optimal solution used (^3,157 of (jif.OOO avail- abl'^ capital and credit. There were 193.2 fanegas of coffee produced. Farm 3 This farm produced good coffee yields v;i th very high costs. The model permitted traditional coffee activities on this farm but tlie five best co rfee-produci ng activities of the region were blocked. The optimal solution contained 1 ess- i n tens I ve coffee production. 59 more- i ntens i ve use of the non-coffee land, and no reduction in coffee acreage. Coffee output was reduced 25 percent from the reported output. This change was accompanied by an increase in net income from ijiS'+JSO to iJi5,5^3. The optimal plan made heavier demands on management with seven producing activities instead of three. Sales included 750 fanegas of coffee, 52.8 quintales of tobacco, 108,^ quintales of corn, ^9,1 quintales of beans, and 16.3 quintales of sesame. The flue-cured tobacco contract row was exhausted as all three manzands pernntted for tobacco vjere planted in the farm model. Permanent labor resources were exhausted in all months except May and October, Coffee harvesting exhausted the labor supply during November, December, January and February, Temporary labor was hired in March, June, July, August and September. The optimal plan used less than (;45,666 of a (^71,100 operating capital and credit constraint. Farm h The fourth farm studied produced coffee and flue-cured tobacco. Tobacco was the chief money earner vjI th coffee grown to supplement income with very low labor inputs. The linear programming model of this farm situation resulted in considerable changes in resource use. Coffee output was increased from 80 to 225 fanegas and tobacco production was reduced from 90 to 46,8 quintales. In addition, corn, beans, and mixed crops were substituted for tobacco. Sales also included 36,7 quintales of corn, 59-9 quintoles of beans, 2,6 quintales of pigeon peas, and 81 pounds of chickpeas. Net returns in the model situation v;ere ,*31,667 v/hlclT greatly exceeded tii-3 (^1^,700 estimate of income under reported resource use. 60 The model used all available land from July through January, all available operating capital and credit, and all permanent labor in April, June, July, August and the harvest irionths froT November through February, Temporary labor was hired in January and August, Family coffee harvesting vjas limited by the family labor supply in December. Hiring labor was not constrained by monthly supervisory limitations which allowed two temporary v^orkers for each family or permanent employee. The tobacco contract allotment was not exhausted. Farm 5 The fifth farm specialized in coffee. The rr;3xi mi za t i on of the linear programming model gave results similar to reported resource use. The net income for the programmed model was (pl6,876. The in- crease over the reported income of (j 15-520 v;as explained by spall savings in the accounting of harvesting costs and the fact that some of the reported expenditures were long-term investments. in the model, permanent labor was fully employed during the harvest period from November through February, All 10 manzanas of land were used and family coffee harvesting v/as limited by the avail- ability of family labor in December, An excess in the operating capital and credit row occurred in the mode] because the rs^ported annual expenditures included som.e long-term investments. The farm produced 190 fanegas of coffee using the hiiyhest yield- ing coffee activity permitted in the model. Farm 6 The sixth farm studied was a small coffee farm with an absentee owner. The farm ..odel allowed coffe*:: yields slightly above t'nose 61 reported by the farm. This reduced the net loss to i~/SO. This loss occurred with an increase in both yield and coffee acreage above the reported numbers. In the model, all four manzanas of land were planted to coffee for profit maximization. This occurred with 0.25 manzanas of new coffee planted. The optimal solution maximized returns to land. Credit and operating capital vje re not limiting in the model, since reported preharvest expenditures were (jA-.OOO compared to a (jZjS^^S optima] preharvest expenditure. A large surplus of permanent labor occurred in all months except during the coffee harvest period. The new coffee planting was not stable in the face of interest changes on the required investment. The rate initially used was 6 percent representing a minimum charge which governiT:ent banks have used in a policy to subsidize agricultural investment. The nev; coffee v;as not planted if interest charges rose 0.8 percent. Beans and sesame were planted instead of coffee. The farm loss increased from C760 to (;i780. Farm 7. The results of programming the seventh farm more than doubled reported net farm income from C3,3^5 to <;7.l^7. In the optimal solution, coffee production v;as expanded with 0.2b manzanas planted to new coffee. Other production activities included v;ere sun-cured tobacco, corn and beans. Optimal output, before parametric changes, was maximized with the production of 62,0 fanegas of coffee, ig quintaies of tobacco, 72.8 quintales of corn, and l8,9 quintales of beans. 62 The optimal production exhausted the credit and operating capital row, land rows from September through January, and the sun-cured tobacco contract. Permanent labor was exhausted in all months except July. Temporary labor was hired in all months except July and August. Labor supervision did not limit hiring temporary labor in any month. The nev^ly planted coffee was not stable when interest charges on investments were increased. Interest charges would block new plantings when the rate was increased 0.1 percent. Farm 8 The eighth farm model results optimized resource use vn th the production of 19 fanegas of coffee, 7.8 quintales of sun-cured tobacco, 2^.0 quintales of corn, 5.^ quintales of beans, and 6.5 quintales of sesame. Optimal net returns were (;;if,005 compared with a reported i ncoine of (;t2,653- Coffee acreage in the optimum progri was the same as the farmer's reported acreage. Credit was severely restricted on this small farm. The shade price indicated that an additional colon of credit or operating capital could return (tl.SS additional net income. Land was fully utilized except in the month of February. Extra labor was available in all months except during the coffee harvest season. No teniporary labor v;as hired. The restriction that aliOv.ed 0,5 manzanas of sun-cured tobacco was not used up. Fa_Qn_^ The nintli fann produced coffee with modern inputs. The model included activi'c'os for hoi'ti cu 1 tu m I cop prodjct'on. The farm maximized income vi'i th coffee monoculLure which yielded <;;86,76l net returns. The former's estiir.ate of net returns v;as s^90,00u, txpendi- -am jow 63 tures for temporary labor vje re underestimated vjhich limited the operating capital and credit row. The monthly labor supplies were fully used in January, February, June, July, September, November and December, Temporary labor was hired in June, July and September. Supervision limitations did not restrict temporary labor hiring. Farm 10 Analysis of the tenth farm showed that an increase in farm in- come could accompany crop diversification. Net returns were increased from (;17,160 to (;i2S,^89 when optimal use of other crops replaced coffee. However, this farm was reportedly upgrading coffee technol- ogy in order to receive ij30,000 expected net returns v;i th coffee monoculture. The optimal cropping pattern included five different crop-grovyi ng activities producing 213.3 fanegas of coffee, i+8,0 tons of tomatoes, 1^8,0 tons of sugarcane, 708,0 quintales of s'wee t potatoes and 5.'^ quintales of chickpeas. Coffee trees were removed from ^,3 manzanas of land. The permanent labor supply v;as Lised up in January, February, April, August, Sepre;Mber, November and December, Temporary workers were hired in January, February, Septem.ber and December, The operating capital c^nd credit con5tr?int v.'as limiting in the model. Supervis'^ry capacicy did not: limit fiiring temporary workers. Farm 11 On the eleventh farm, programmed optimal solutions did not change cofpee acreage from ihe reported land use. Other crops replaced pineapples. The reported net returns of i-^?.,3'dO exceeded the optima] income of (j2'i-,536 of the model. This difference occurred because the model contained fruit prices for industrial use while tha farmer produced 5-3 manzonas of pineapple foi' the fresh fruit market in Gk San Jose. The high domestic market prices of fruits and vegetables were not used in the model, since these prices could not be received if any significant portion of coffee resources were shifted into horticultural production. Sales to maximize net revenue included 100.0 fanegas of coffee, 2.0 quintales of beans, 710.9 quintales of limes, 13-0 tons of tomatoes, 0.8 tons of green peppers, 236.0 tons of sugarcane and 25^+. 5 quintales of swee tpota toes . Land was fully utilized from November through April. Permanent labor was fully utilized in all months except October. Temporary labor vias hired in January, February, April, June, August, September and December. The capacity to supervise labor v^jas not an effective restriction in any mionth; however, slack supervisory capac- ity was reduced to 29. '4 hours in January. The operating capital and credit row limitation was exhausted. Relational limitations v^ere not res tr i cti ve. Farm 12 The twelfth farm v;as programmed v;i th only the poorer coffee- producing activities of the Alajuela region. The farm reported poor coffee yields averaging 10 fanegas per manzana. The programmed optimal solution contained the traditional coffee activity vjhich yielded nine fanegas per manzana. The activity based on the reported resource use v\;as dominated by another coffee-producing activity. Net returns vjere maximized with tlie production of coffee, corn and beans and limes v;hich netted iJ ,07^ in the model. These returns were higher than the ^6,122 calcul.ned from the farmer report. Farm out- put included 22,5 fanegas of coffes, 2^4.1 quintales of corn, ^.8 quintales of beans and 717.2 quintales of limes. 65 Excess permanent labor occurred in all months except the coffee harvest period. No temporary labor was hired. All coffee was harvested with family labor. Credit v/as severely restricted. Farm 13 The thirteenth farm was programmed using tvjo different sets of fruit prices representing industrial prices v;i th and without a processing plant located in the Acosta region. Two completely dif- ferent diversification pictures are presented since it is questionable whether or not the area could support a processing plant. First, higher fruit prices were used to evaluate diversification alternatives, Limes viere priced at ^ilS.OO per quintal, blackberries at (jl.OO per pound and oranges at (;i^,00 per hundred. The results of profit maximization in the model showed a sizable departure from the reported resource use. This does not dispute a theory of farmer profit rrotivation since completely different horticultural alternatives were placed in the model. Nevertheless, the model shows that if fruit prices v.'3 re moderately high and stable, considerable changes would occur and coffee output would be reduced on farm '3. Profits in the model wer-e maximized with <;89,9^8 netted from mixed coffee and 1 I m.e production. Coffee tree destruction was programmed for 32.9^ manzanas. Credit was limited, causing both semi- abandoricd m.ethods and traditional low-yield methods of coffee to be used in coffee production. Permanent labor '..'as fully utilized in January, February, May, July, August, September. October, November and December. Temporary labor was hired in January, February, May, July, August and September. The lim.it on superv'ision for temporary workers was not effective. 66 Farm production was comprised of 195,6 fanegas of coffee and 17,780 quintales of limes. This coffee output v^as reduced from the present output of 900 fanegas. However, without favorable fruit prices, the maximum income for farm 13 was <;67,69'^, Therefore, the reported income of i;i66,878 closely approximated the maximum of the model when only traditional crops vjere grown and coffee output was 900 fanegas. Other sales Included 333.5 quintales of corn and 126.5 quintales of beans. In the model, a higher-yielding corn and bean activity substituted for the corn and bean activity actually reported in use. in the second analysis, low fruit prices were programmed at ^9,00 per quintal of limes, (;^0,50 per pound of blackberries and ^3.00 per hundred oranges. With the lower fruit prices, the available credit and operating capital row was not a limiting factor. All coffee land remained in coffee but no new coffee was planted. The most advanced technology permitted by the model was used to produce corn and beans. Permanent labor was exhausted in all months except April and June; hovjever, temporary labor was hired only in January, Ma!-ch, July, August, September and October. All but 96 fanegas of coffee vjere harvested with contract labor. Fa_rnn_Uf As with the preceding farm, the fourteenth farm was prograrp,med using high and 1 ov^ fruit prices. With the higher fruit prices, opt I ini i^a tion of the model resulted in considerable departure from reported practices. Although no coffee trees vjcre rem.oved, output of coffee v.'as reduced from 70.0 to 18. ^^ fanegas v/i th coffee produc- tion activities using low-yield and sen! -abandoned miethods. Nine 67 manzanas of lines utilized the non-coffee land and 3,600 quintales of limes were produced. Net returns in the model were ii,lh,121. The farm reported income was much lower with i.\\ ,kkS netted from tradi- tional grain crops and common coffee practices. The operating capital and credit row were severely limited in the model with a marginal return of iji.Sl per (jl.OO of credit. Per- manent labor was exhausted except in March and April, The model resulted in hired labor in January, February, Kay, June, July, August and September, Labor supervision was not a limiting factor. The optimal solution in the model for farm 1 '^ v-jas completely different when lower fruit prices were used to represent alternatives without a nearby processing plant. The maximization of net returns with traditional crop alternatives resulted in 70.0 fanegas of coffee output. Maximum net returns in the model vjere higher than reported returns, ^16,718 compared to <;! 1,^+46. The increase v/as accomplished with higher returns to corn and beans vjhich were programmed v^;ith moderately poor yields that greatly exceeded reported Farm production. Nevertheless, insofar as coffee production was concerned, the model results coincided with the actual reported production. Maximum net returns occurred with the production of IQ.O fanegas of coffee, 261,0 quintales of corn and 99-0 quintales of beans. Operating capital v;5S limiting and the family labor supply was ex- hausted in all months except March, April and June, Labor v.-as hired in May, August, September, October, r-'ovember and December. Farm 1^ The fifteenth farm also was given two different -"^ruit price situations. V/i tli high fruit prices used first to represent production 68 potentials given a processing plant in the region, the farm model maximized net returns at iS,'-^59. in comparison, reported production netted only ii,^f03- Profits were maximized by shifting 0,26 manzanas of coffee into lime production. Farm output included 17,^ fanegas of coffee and 105.9 quintales of limes. The farm model used all credit and operating capital available. Labor was fully used only from October through February during the coffee harvest. Land vjas fully utilized and no temporary labor was hired. Of the C5,^59 netted on the farm, (^2,353 were received from off-farm coffee harvesting. When lower fruit prices were used in the linear programming analysis of farm 15, all land was planted to coffee. Farm production in the model slightly exceeded reported coffee output. Income was above chat reported because the model included temporary outside income from coffee harvesting as part of farm income. Of tfie (;i5 , 209 net returns, (^2,308 was income from coffee harvesting work on other farms. Commonly grown coffee replaced the reported poorer yielding coffee-orange activity. Coffee production maximized the returr.s to land and harvest time labor. Credit v.'as not a limiting resource vjj-ien low fruit prices were used in the model. The family labor supply exceeded all rr.onthly demands for labor and no labor was hired. The excess family labor was sold during the coffee harvest period ar.d was unused the remainder of the year. Twenty fanegas of coffee were pror'uced with Che optimal use of resources. Farm 16 The sixteenth farm v^as also programmed v.m th liigh and low fruit 69 prices. The farm had reported 7.5 fanegas of coffee production from 1.5 manzanas of coffee. When high fruit prices were used, the maximization of profits shifted resources into lime production and coffee land was utilized in semi -abandoned coffee production. Net returns reached ikj^Oy when maximized which surpassed the (;;1,339 cal- culated as expected income with reported resource use. However, (j2,273 out of the (;i^,307 represented harvest labor sales. Credit was severely restricted when high fruit prices reflected a strong local market. Over (;t5.30 marginal returns were estimated per colon of additional credit. Almost 1,2 manzanas of land were idle in the optimal solution. Output included 3.0 fanegas of coffee, 382.4 quintales of limes, i8,2 quintales of corn and 27.3 quintales of beans. Permanent labor was fully employed only during the coffee harvest and no temporary workers were hired. When low fruit prices were used in the programming model, limes were excluded and resources were allocated to traditionally grown coffee and low-yielding corn and bean activities. Credit was severely restricted with a marginal return for operating expenditures estimated at <:3.22 per (;^1.00. Profits were maximized with 0,77 manzana of land idle. Excess permanent labor occurred in al] months except during the coffee harvest. No temporary v/orkers were hired. Optim.al sales included 3.0 fanegas of coffee, 5'-+.0 quintales of corn and 32.2 quintales of beans. Income v;as maximized at (^3,612, of v;hlch C2,1'45 came from labor selling for coffee harvest. Pol i cy Analysl s Education for Better Farm Manaqemen t The first section of this chapter compared reported and optimal 70 programmed resource use given the price and credit relationships faced by the farmers without a positive policy to foster crop diversifica- tion. Nevertheless, the changes in resource use may be attributed to a general policy of better farmer education and expanded extension vjork that would be required before part of the alternatives programmed could be put into practice. Therefore, the first policy consideration to be considered repre- sents education for better farm management. It is often heard that farmers produce coffee because of non-econcmlc motivations, that they are reluctant to change, or that they maintain traditional cropping patterns out of ignorance. Table 2 shows comparisons betv/een the reported and optimal values for net returns and for coffee outputs. The results do not indicate that irrational overproduction of coffee was prevalent. Of the 16 farms studied, only two farms demonstrated overproduction of coffee. Overproduction on farm 3 could be attrib- uted to overi ntens i fi cation where returns could be increased by reducing inputs and yields. The huge quantities of fertilizer re- ported represented either mismanagement or hidden investment. Overproduction on farm 10 occurred because either sugarcane or horti- culture gave returns high enough to replace part of the moderately high-yielding coffee. The lovjer programmed coffee output on these tvjo farms v;as countered by higher output on other farms. V/hile the sample Is too small to support broad generalizations, some overproduction of coffee beyond that quantity dictated by strict Hidden investment in this case nay arise wh.en increased anniial expenditures occur for a short period before yields are increased to f ul 1 potent i a1 . 71 Table 2, Comparisons betvyeen reported and optimal incomes and coffee output Net returns Coffee output Farm^ Reported Optimal Reported optimal (colcne?) (col ones) ( fanegas) (fanegas) 1 22,500 19,781 82.8 82.8 2 15,250 18,025 179.9 193.2 3 34,130 35,543 1 ,000.0 750.0 k 14,700 31,667 80.0 225.0 5 15,520 16,877 190.0 190.0 6 - 6,760 760 56.3 76.0 7 3,345 7,147 45.0 62.0 8 2,653 4,005 15.0 19.0 9 20,000 86,761 1 ,000.0 997.2 10 17,160 29,489 300.0 213.3 11 42,980 24,536 100.0 100.0 12 6,122 7,078 25.0 22.5 13A 66,878 89,948 900,0 195.6 13B 66,878 67,694 900.0 900.0 ]kA . n,4iuS 24,222 70.0 18,4 14b ]],kk6 16,718 70.0 70.0 15A 1,403 5,459 10.0 17.4 15B 1,403 5,209 10.0 20.0 16A 1,339 4,307 7.5 3.0 16b 1,339 3,612 7.5 9.0 "The letters A and B are used to designate different fruit pricing used in Acosta. are used ro indicate the situations using high f rui t pr 1 ces f rui t pr i ces , :nd B's are used to indicate the situations usina low 72 profit maximization is indicated. Most of the potential for income improvement occuiT'^d vji th the land not planted to coffee. Labor selling activities for the coffee harvest made sizable contributions to the higher optimal incomes of the smeller farms. Of the 20 farm s i tuat ions studied, three reported higher incomes than the optimal permitted in the model. In farm 1 and farm 9 this difference was due to a lovjer wage cost estimation in the farmer report than was permitted in the mode). More significantly, the re- duced optimal income on farm 11 came about because the model only allowed pineapple sales for export or industrial use vjhile the farm produced for a much higher domestic fresh-fruit market. Markedly increased incomes were accompanied by reductions in coffee output only V'jhen high return fruit or vegetable crops v/ere considered as alternatives. Thus the higher incom.es are associated with higher risks. Optimal allocation of resources reduced coffee output 3.06 percent on the eight farms of the Palmares-San Ramon area, and G.kS percent on the four farms of the Alajuela area. For Acosta, optimal resource allocation increased coffee output l,i6 percent when low fruit prices were used but decreased coffee output 76,26 percent when high fruit prices v;ere used, A sizable reduction occurred in the Acosta output only when high yielding alternatives were compared with low yielding coffee. Changes which reduced coffee output brought activities into production vjhich utilized more modern inputs than the alternative crops usually receive in Costa Rica, This gives rise to a question of whether or not the same relationships would exist if new coffee growing activities represented high.er levels of technology in coffee 73 production. In order to keep the model representative of current technological proficiency, certain high-yielding coffee activities were flagged from use in 17 of the 20 farm situations. Then parametric programming vas used to increase coffee transfers until reported yields of the better farms v;ere equaled. The results shoued that on some farms modernization Vv'ould be justified if over 60 percent of antici- pated yields were obtainable. In the Alajuela and Palmares-San Ramon areas, it would pay most farms to adopt modern inputs if over 80 per- cent of the recorded yields vjere obtainable. in Alajuela technological change permitted yield increases from 20 to 25 fanegas per manzana. In Palmares-San Ramion the yields were increased from 19 to 27.6 fanegas per manzana. Yields were increased from 10 to 1^ fanegas per m-inzana in Acosta. The results of the programmed technological advances are given in Table 3- In the Alajuela and Palmares-San Ramon farm situations, optimal coffee output v;as increased ll.h percent and farm income was increased 110,23 percent when higher-yielding coffee activities modified the output of nine farms. In the Acosta programs, coffee output was increased I98.8I percent and net income vjas increased 9.38 percent when technological changes for coffee were permitted in the fo'jr farm situations when high fruit prices were used. Given low fruit prices, coffee output only increased 15-98 percent but in- come increased 2'^.,98 percent in the Acosta fari^ siiuatioos. Higher levels of technology bro'jght si';ali increases In coffee acreage on a number of the farms. The planting of nev.' coffee was limited by credit restrictions. The gains i .i programired income were sufficiently high to motivate change if the im.proved technology can Ih Table 3- The effects of improving coffee production technology on coffee production and income Coffee output 1 ncomes ^ a Farm Current I mproved Current Improved technology technology technology technology (fanegas) ( fanegas) (colones) (colones) 3 750.0 1 ,i462.8 35,543 138,168 h 225.0 it25.0 31,667 62,013 5 190.0 276.0 16,877 29,739 6 76.0 110. ^4 760 4,583 7 62.1 9'+.3 7,147 10,979 8 19.0 27.6 4,005 5,720 10 213.3 281.4 29,489 38,460 n 100.0 120.0 24,536 27,989 12 22.5 60.1 7,078 9,440 13A 195.6 656.0 89,948 101 ,272 !3B 900.0 1,032.1 67,694 90,709 l^+A 18. ir 18.4 24,222 24,274 14b 70.0 94.5 16,718 18,361 15A MA 23.0 5,459 5,707 15B 20.0 23.0 5,209 5.707 I6A 3.0 3.0 4,307 4,307 i6B 9.0 9.0 3,612 3.612 The letters A and B are used to designate different fruit pricing L'sed in Acosta. A's are used to indicate the situations using high fruit prices and B's are used to indicate the situations using low fruit pr i ces. 75 increase production to the levels reported on the better farms. The higher yields obtainable in Alajuela and Acosta resulted in greater increases in income in comparison with the Acosta farms. Coffee production, therefore, is expected to increase unless positive aids to diversification or production controls are put into effect. Comparisons between optimal coffee production and maximum net returns for traditional versus new enterprises are shown in Table k. On the Alajuela farms, returns from sugarcane approached those of horticultural crops and optimal coffee output vjas net reduced when the new crops were included among the alternatives. Hovjever , incomes v.'ere increased where coffee yields were limited to 20 fanegas per manzana. Actually, the higher credit requirements of the horticultural alternatives caused the optimal coffee tree destruction to be lower when horticultural crops were included on Farm 10. in the Acosta farm situations the exclusion of fruit production alternatives lowered optimal income and caused a sizable increase in coffee output. Farm 13 and farm 1^ had sufficient capital and credit to respond to fruit production opportunities with sizable increases in income. The addiLional incone potential of fruits and vegetables v;as limited on the smaller Farms by a shortage of operating capital and credi t. Taxation or Price Reduction The stability of coffee production in farm management plans v;as further examined vnth price declines parcmetri ca 1 ly prograrnmed into each fariH situation. Table 5 shov/s the effect of price declines on coffee output. Reduced output v;ith ftS.OG per fanega price declines was limited to the blocking of new plantings of coffee trees and the 76 Table k. Comparisons of optimal incomes and coffee outputs with traditional versus new enterprises on farms in Alajuela and Acosta Coffee output Net i ncome Tradi tiona] New Tradi tional New Farm enterprises enterpri ses enterpri ses enterpri ses (fanegas) (fanegas) (colones) (colones) 9 997.2 997.2 86,761 86,761 10 163.8 213.3 22,586 29.489 11 100.0 100.0 22,239 24,536 12 22.5 22.5 7,003 7,078 13 900,0 196.5 67,694 - 89,948 1^ 70.0 18.4 16,718 24,222 15 20.0 17.4 5 , 209 5,459 16 9.0 3-0 3,612 4,307 11 (1) -^ o co' d fv^ J-" M3'-— o>, — „ ^-LA <^^'^_C5 00f^OLA<^vlcs40Lr\rslOvO — csiooo ^ !^' I^ ^ ° ~ '"^ '~~^ 1^ f^ o csj fv^ J-' tv^ _' co' d CO m r-1 d (.; d _i\cM_ cTicM— — a^ CO c-j o a o o o o CM ,-■> o LA vo o -d- o -:! o o o S ??^ 1^ ^ "^ ',$')! ^ '^ '^^ "^^ <^' ^-^ •=> oi o (-1 d c-; en oo O^ u^ CM rj- l\ vr) — O^ — CO CM 0-\ O — t-^ .- CNI — r-- CM _ en c'-i — — en CJ n-i J- Lr\K£> ■ OO (Ti O ro < M <; 03 < m c'"> -:f -:t L.n i-A vo \J3 78 substitution of corn and beans for low-yielding coffee on farm ]k. Taxes up to $10.00 per fanega would have little effect on coffee out- put of the farrrs programmed. Except for the newly planted coffee, coffee production was not responsive to price declines up to .jZO.OO per fanega. High-yielding coffee and semi -abandoned coffee v.'ere the most stable. With high coffee yields, the alternatives are poorly competitive and with very low-yields, stability is assured by severe credit limitations. Resources were shifted av^^ay from coffee when the coffee price fell to new market price levels. Table 6 shows the effect of price declines on coffee acreage. Coffee acreage was more stable than coffee output. Coffee land was notably more stable on the smaller farms as price declines were pro- grammed. The effect of price declines on farm incomes is shown in Table J. Price declines reduced income more rapidly than output and had the strongest ePFect on those farms highly specialized in coffee produc- tion. For example, given a ^hO per fanega price decline, income fell 5^ percent on the three largest coffee producing farms and only 22 percent on the farms vji th optimal production less than 100 ganegas. Met returns on farm 2, farm 5, farm 9 and farm 13B, all of v/hich specialized in coffee production, v;e re reduced over 50 percent by a CSO per fanega price decline. 0^ those farms specializing in coffee production, only on farm 10 did d i ve rs i f i ca !:i on possibilities hold income above fjO pcixent of initial levels when price v;as reduced 25 percent. In the Acosta farm situations, high fruit prices resulted in both higher incomes and greater income stability in the face of coffee price declines. The effect of a price decline on income was 79 a c o LTV o -d- o ■o O -u- ■u n t/1 0) ro u -n .— v_ 4-J Cl < L. ooooj-Lno^ooo-^cooi_'Ncnooo-d"-J"r--uALri c^^-MDoar^cNr^ — MDCsJOOvitv-iO^^vO — — — — — — CM LA oof^oooooour\coou-\o>cx3cooj-ouPiLr\ (v-v r~- -J" LP, o r^ (^ J- cr\ LTV r^ OOvDOOCOOOO — OL/\'3^0000O-d-OuPiLri oo r--~ J- LA O OA oA ^ — — Or^LACMfv-vvD^r^ — csl. — . — -5" LA MD OOOOOCOOOO-4'OlaI^-J-OOO-TOUAUA cAr^OUAOf^rA— OO^i-A^J" — ^r-~. — CM. — — l-A — -— J- LA C30 c (T3 c OOOOO00OOOr^OLAr^-d-OOr-~.OLAUA CA r^ O LA O OA rA ' LA . OOLAtM-:!--- r^r--— CM — — -:r — LACO OOOOOCCOOOJ^OLAOOOOr^OLALA OAf — cbLAOoArA^ — OOLAAj:^Or^.l~~^ — CM — — LA -cr — LA CTl ooooocoooor^. Oi-'>oooor--.ou^uA oAr^O LAOrArA — OCi LACM r^^a r^r^ — cm — — LA -J- — LA en O O O O O O CA O O r^ O u\ O O O O r-- O U'"\ LA >-A r^ O LA O -J- rA — o o ja o! r- c "-- r^ — Ai — . — UA • J- — LA a> CM CA J- LA VC 1^- CO CTl Cj t' CO ■< CO <: cj <: ca c^-' rA rA J" J" UA '-j'> VD vO 80 o u fO en (1) c 1_ 0) U Q. 0) CL 0) e o o E u n3 4-J E O -Q r o ■u- u T3 C.) O • O LTv-d" ^r'^o^cMrv-^c■'^(^J — Or^uAcnvOcsiJ-LAr^Cvi — cm u-\ 00 CN4 r-^J- -d- rr\ CO o o^Lof^ a^c^t^J"-d"-3"f*^ <^ CM c — C30 CM CM . — crir^MD-:t r~~.o uncM cm r^v.0000000 o o^oo crii^cx) vO Cr\(-oo^r-^f^vDCO r-^cv-\r^l — ^r^LAu-\— vD OOOCO -3-c\JooocMvDOOCMcoi-r\La— r^ — lti — ooJ- — cm vo 0 LA c^\ vT^ r^-d- or\ vo , — 0 r— CM , -d- CM CM vo i^-d- o^-d--d-d-J- CO fv-i CM r— OA CTit^-d" r--cxD Lr>r^-d- uamd rov£) Ovo o o or^cN f~^-d"'-r^ — (^i-r\-d"-d"oAOu-vu^cocNLAO — -d" <^oo — o^-d-J-oocMLn-d-or^-M3r^o^vDCM(v^ r^ CM (V-i LA — CM 1-A OA vD rr\ . — v^ U^ C^~! C^J LA — r--\ -d" -d" -d- -J- CXD -d- CM — CA o -u- 0) in oj IJ^— cv-iCOvD LALA — ^CMv^ODr^Otv-vOCM 0-iI~^CM t^^-d"r^r^OOrAi — cMrACMODa~iLAvD' — OOrA — — LA — O CM O VC 00 CM LA MD CA to CO PA — CO CVl J- coJ- o r-^rACMv^o oAvo LACM^>.o o^<^LAu-^-d•-d■rA — . — CMCM — vDtNCM COJ-Csl. — I rA rA CO 1^ r^ OA LA lj~v m vO VD PA CM -d" l\ ■ J- VO ON P-- CM LA en -cr ' — r^ c> 1^- — 00 uA o"^ la cr> o^ < a c>j oo o r-. cm o^ o o -d" o^, -d" lA cx! r--- cA u^ 00 a"i vD o o CM o CM u^ COvOCOO^J"— MDCAvOi^^rAvD^^ — — CMCM. — r^CMCM CO I CO -d" >.0 LA LA -J- LA CM — CA r^O^PACMr-~-vOOOLACMOM30-d-O^OOAJo>iCMp^ vo LAo^-d" CM oA^ — r-^cM cA^o i'-^a~\CMvx) r^o o^^,o PA o r^ LA o". — CO o^ 1^ -d- o O', cr\ — — c^ CA — CM LA o^ r^ — o u--. — — OA iv-, . \ O O-^ — 00 ~-i- ^O CO PA J- vo i-A LA -d" cv^ ro iNl CM CO vD '■>; — — LA p^, r^ i\ o r~- LA — en vo CO 00 -t PM CO m o-\ i-^ cm 00 CM _J- vD 00 vO J O vO OD CA l\ ..+ o"\ AJ — I A O O — r\ o LA vo 03 t^ — O 1-^ -d- u^ o o^ o CM r^. -d- CM CA vo O^ 00 UA ■ — vO — ■ — PA PA . — 1^ -T - o T> J" r~- o^ r-.. -d" oo iM CM 00 VC CM ir\ J- PA c~-l PA J- 1J~\ vD r^ CO o^ o CN f A PA -^1" ^1" LA LA > O > O 81 greater on the farms from the Palmares-San Ramon area where expandable alternatives fell further behind coffee in terms of net returns. The alternative crops that increased first as coffee prices were programmed downward are shown in Table 8. In the Palmares-San Ramon area the farms first responding to a price decline were those with unused tobacco allotment. Among the Alajuela farms studied the larger farms responded first to a price decline. This also held true among the farms from Acosta although irregularities occurred with respect to which set of fruit prices vjere used. Payments for Coffee Removal The programmed effect upon coffee output of annual payments for coffee tree removal is shown in Table 9. Farm 1, farm 2 and farm 9 were not responsive to removal subsidies because of high returns to coffee. Farm 16 was not responsive because of severe credit limita- tions. Annual payirients equal to 20 percent of gross coffee earnings per manzana viere effective in changing optimal resource allccatioii in five of the 20 farm, situations studied. Given a 25 percent discounted price for 25 percent of the output of coffee, the payment of 20 per- cent of base gross returns ccula be made for the withdrawal of coffee production without extra taxes or loss to coffee producers. The following formula can be used for calculating a self-paying subsidy for coffee removal. Let the coffee price be unch.anged as coffee in excess of tiie quota is taken out of production. Then: PT + (P - DP)N = PT T + N T + SN 82 Table 8. Alternative crops increased first by declines in coffee prices Farm 1 2 3 k 5 6 7 8 9 10 l] 12 13A 13B ]kA I'fB I5A 158 16A 16B Price reduction per faneqa (col ones) 100 91 ko 15 57 58 90 15 21 22 ^3 60 ]k ]k 25 55 29 58 iOO 32 Crop increased None Beans, sesame Beans, corn Tobacco, beans Beans, sesame Beans, sesame Castorbeans , mi 1 k Tobacco Sugarcane, beans Tomatoes, sugarcane Limes, peppers Limes Limes Corn, beans Limes Corn, beans L i me s Corn, beans None Corn, beans 83 > o E 0) u (U (U o I. o c 0) E 03 C C c o (J ■D O I- Q. CU o en I- o o -T • r— ■u c o 1/1 TO 0) o U1 o CM u . — 01 •o (D 14- o -o c (1) o o 0) o JT • +J , — ■(.J ■M fD -U ~C> ra cr c/l o ■i-» o C GO (1) ■u TJ Q a c D C o ._ o +-1 vO c •<-ll o <_) o o J- ■o (/I [ *-' c Q) LU ^ I'D ci O z. E rtl '^1 (t3 OOc~-JOr^r^OOOCN|(X>Oi-r\OOCOOslrOCNCXDOO CNIfv^O(v-\CMOr^O"A'~^r^OtN^>OOCNlLACXD>Or*^Cr» COcn J"-d" LPi— (Tiv£) 'NloO— -d" — oocN4r^oOLr\OOOCNloocriLr\a>oJ-r^cMcooo cNj rv> CO CO ^ o r~-- a^ ''^ f^ f^ ^J CO ^ r'\ la co md o^ o^ CO O \ O v£) vT LPv — O^ ^ — ^ tN — 3" — — c\J . — — (ys — c^ 00C^c-IOO(^OOCNIO-:tLrvCA 3'Lr\c40000 c^J n-\' — <>J o — r-.cr,r~^csi c-\tN'oo-d" r»-\cMoovo c^cri coc^^vX)a^o^^-~|-A — o^t^r-^-cvicMj-— ^D • — — C\l — ^ — (T\ ' — ra COtNloOj-OrOOOCMOOLAO^I^MDOCsloOOO CNirv^csl — o — I^^(J^r-~CNIocsIc0^■~O(>~^O0GvD0-\c^^ cOCTivDCNJcrvr^LA— o^-d'OCMcsiLTv — r-~ — C0CMCNIOO(V~iOOCNJCNJOLP, OJCMJ-O-ctoOOO ^^lo^(7^L^^O — r-~o"it^r^OCNiroJ-cOOr^MDcao~\ ooa~iM3CMcnr-^La— criooocsir^a>, — r^r— — — v£)Cvl— |j~,_„ — UA COrsloOOrv^OOoar^OLPiiNloj-O-i-OOO coa~\LAcMo^r^i-pv' — (T^' — cc-4(v^, — — r^ — c^j — I^ CNJ . — 0~, CJ — . — 00 ooc>iooOf^oocM(v-, OLr\voo-a-o-4"COO CNi | cNi _ — a^ — CNI (v-1 _-J- i_A vO r-^ 00 rjN O O B 0) 0) (D U- >+- o o u o Q. C c C o 10 0) o C o o o ro E c (U e > 03 Q cr c c o o 00 CO .^. .-^^ -^ 0_ t-^ cr^ rvj o o - LA LA O J- c^.^ o^ oo CO no r^ — — u-\ o^ _ CO-d-CNJ rAOCM — rr\ cTi 00 cPi CM r^ — — -d" <>~i > — rv..j- 1"^ CN OA 0~\ CM — r-~o rococo i~^— O r-^o lao laod o-,ooodA^vo -± r^ CM \-d- o — cr,co cNj ~ vo ^ J" OA — 00 OA CM CM CO CM . — ...'^°^, '^— O I^U-iLAO CA-d- CM r^r-~-04 fAvO c o o a^ CO r^ ' — \X) ' — — rA rA — 00 rA J CA CM 1^ f^ f^ -^ VO LA lA -J- — r\ Tsi ~ i-A o o •u o o o -d- O u c E a r^ooovooor-.— or^cMu-xocsJvorMi-^vOcMcAvO CPlCO LA — vO ■ CA CA . — 00 CM ^ C^A CM I^O — -CfvD LALAJ- — I — CM — rA COcMJ-vDOOCO-d-O^OCMrv^FiCo — r~-.O.j-\vDOOr-..-Or-^cMLAO~vo O^ 00 LA — MD — ' — CA CA ■ — CM CO vo o^ r^ c^j cv c — u■^ o o . — CM r»^ vxi CM c>~i M3 r~^ J- \jD — J- iX) fA CM r^OAO^-J->jO LALAJ- O vo CM ^- OA en ra LA ~ vD ■ — ' — CA f'S . — '^ ^ ^ S? -^ 1^ O;-^ f^- -^ ^O UA LA -J-" cv^ CO C si CM 00 ^-0 CM -O 03 E 1_ 03 ^0A_-t LA.or~.cOc^O-rM^^:^^< ^<55 ■a (J o -a OI^OOCslrM(~oco r-^CTv-d-vXl — Lr\-J" — cOrv-ACOC\lcslOCs)J- — . — La — — -J- csl ro-d" cvi — o-J"r^CNiracM — r-^LTvcMLPi' — t^-d"-d"J"(^f^ 00 — cNir^cMvOLA — o^. r^i — csicocr^f~^Ln — — — M3 — . — LACNI CMJ- cor~^r^i^^J"c^ocr-, oooi-rvLrvr^J"00 vO vO O f^ CN! tNl OCO tv~, — r-^J--d-J- rv-iCviv,OMD POCNI u-NLTvrv-vvO oOf^cNcoJ" r^LTv — -d" [^.oocNjj- r^csi la — — , — r-^ — . — VOCM CSILA COmDOO — LAO — -Cj-OA — LAj"Li^-a'Crv(^A(^"\00^ csi cao tN o^-J" r^r---rACO cvi cm la, r^o c^ r^r-^oAco OOLALAC^, LAI — LA' — OALACr\CSIrA_3-i — LA — — — r-~-' — ■ — i^cNj csivo ooLiAO^cri00oooocr\LACNr^oo^(T\CT~iOO CNlJ-or^J-vO^-^(J^c~>lJ"CT^cNcMcX)J■csloooooAcn cor--j~, a~>r-^r--~LA — OJ- cticnij- — ■ — la — — — (->-• — — oocvj csr^ COCMO^ — OOOOr^LAOLALACNIOCX)vOOOO ^^Jtv-^o^-^OM3'^CT^OOOc-^lcXlcslJ■LAC7^0rAO^ C0CriLAO,l — LA — rv,CNIOCMLA(J\ — LA' — Csj — i^cNj — cocNj' — csir~^ OOcMOvOOOOOOtv-iOLAOAOO LA O O O CNl OAO C^O-£) t^CnLACAO C^IJ"CX3-d" C^OO O PACTA cocni-A — cnr^LA — oa — ocnio^O' — ^ — cni — r^cNi— c^csi. — CMCX3 COOJOOOOOOCM O LA V.0 o -j- O - J- o o o CM (v^ o LA O vO '■^ O^ r^ i^A O csi LA O' 'JO O r- O r>~\ (T\ cx) CA LA c^-i cn r^- v£) ' — m — o CN/ c^, o — r^ — csi . — r^CSI^ CTvCNl. — — 0"A CM c-A-J- LTvsO r-^ CO o^ o CM i^~i rA -zs CO <; CQ ■3 O 03 > 0) O u c QJ C E o 01 CT ro -t-j c Q. X . COOOMD o^roo CTvO r^O rAv£) r^-d" I^^CvJ-j-J- LA LA vDCT^cr^c^cncr\oo ooo — cni la-J-^vxj-j rAf*Ar--.r^ o^Aoa^^^<^c~^tNlv£)LAcMfv^cOl — cmo~\-;1'-3"' — — — csl, — , — oocsj I CO \D ■ — v_DcriJ" cr\-:l"oocsjviD, — oo — r^t^cArAa% — OLr>-d-LAr^r^LALA— — ■ — CNI r.1 00 LA -J- vD -J" -:?■ O — • — -T (-A — — r^CTir^vDvp r^r-vo rA — oo cm o cno~iLACOco r^o r--cT\CM — J- cJ^oo\ri0^cv^^-~-00LAt-^vD — — ' d^ -d" r--~LAcr\v^ r^-d"vD o^fACNivjD cnj ov^r^_ [^i — la-^" -d" G~\CO t^ — — CM CNI .- LAcvjoo — cr\-d-J- — J- CNI — LA-J- O CM -d- _J CNI CNI VD i>ALA O 00 -3" O LA J- J- O v£) O O 1^ CA LA CM CA Lf\ CA — — lA rsl — vD CNI v£) CA • — LA '- I^. 00 LA CM CM VO J" • — (A -d" -3" CM CM in c o O LAI^CA — CX)0 — -d--d-CNI^LA— LA00CMOOcAa> — COJ- — r-^MD — OOlJ^.— cv-\i^rslCOCMC^Cr\fALA CM^ LALA — r^N0CMCX)cvJJ-v£)J-r^cMrAOOCMcrv ■o -i-i (U . — \- c L.' ro O q; in ■i;; (t) c lO ro r-^ LA LA r^ LA fA CM — MD CA -d" LA CM \^ CM CM LACnrr^. O-d- LALAtACSI 'Xl LA CM — r J LA cA ij^ r-~ O O — -d" O VD v£) o ev^ vo r^ 1-^ cr\ ' — l~-- LACMj-r^'-^vX — I — csicnj-.— — vOc^JLAJ-oo^r^ LAOLAOoor^oo-d"r--~r^cNj. — couacO' — cmcmla — 00 CO lA o^ '^D rA CM — NO CA CM vO rA vO MD cr\ ■ — la la la I'A cv> r^ CNi CM r-~ LA CM — olaoaJ- r^ovooo r^-d" rAr^rp,r^c^i o (^iT\a~\-d" LACM_d"cor~~.vocorA' — vooc^' — r--c-vicOLAO.j-cn LAO LA-d'OO r^C^r^TNCM C7^LA|■^C^JCM CTii^C^I a~\rA CT^ CO LA O MD ' — — rA f A — ^o r^CncX) rAMD rALAr>-. LTiLALAcAOA r--~ CM c^l (X5 vX) CM — ■ — LA cA r-^- r^ o r^ LA -- en vo oo oo J- 'm co cr\ c"i r^ cm ro CM -J- vo r-. o -J" O v;3 CO J" r~- J- o~, ;M ,•• ia O CD r— r~ o uA '^ 00 r--^ — o r^ -d" lp, O c^ O c-vi r^ .^ oj (>a vO CTl CO LA — vD , — . — CA CV-\ ^ r^--j vo 'JA -d" r~-- G~\ r^ J^ vD Lr\ LA J- rA oo CM CM CO U'J C>J r— O — CNJ CA CA -d" <." I-A I A \.0 U) 93 use V'vas reduced only when new plantings occurred in the model. Semi- abandonment of coffee did not use up restricted credit and the stabil- ity of land use is shown in Table 15. The shadow prices of the credit row are given in Table 16. These showed very high returns to additional credit especially as credit re- ductions occurred. Before short-term credit effectively '"educed coffee production, the marginal returns greatly exceeded the usurious rates of money lenders. Movement of Labor The possibility that a higher demand for off-farm labor could shift resources out of coffee production was considered. Table 17 shows a movement of family workers in 11 of 17 farm situations having family labor, Hovjever, coffee output was not changed in 15 of the 17 cases. On farm 10, moving workers vjould increase optimal coffee pro- duction and on farm 13B, the movement brought about a slight decrease in programmed coffee output. Higher family income from new jobs in- dicated that family workers rec^iveci less than l3gal vjace rates, A similar inquiry also Indicated that more permanent labor w3s hired than needed for maximum net returns. The relaxation of labor inflexibility showed that 12 of 20 farms could increase profits by encouraging employee m.obi 1 i ty to other jobs. As slTOvjn in Table 18, coffee production vias influenced on only two of 17 farms. The movement oi' labor altered farm output on ?ome farms but the effects upon coffee output was negligible. Of the farms studied, the smaller farms have larger percentages of excess labor. This may be necessary to assure 3:T|jle l^arvesting labor on a nurber of the farms although motivations other than profit 'laxi mi zat i on appear to be man- i fes ted. 9^ 0) -■a u -a o ■n > 1/1 o \- > 0} (U o w c N c E E O un J3 o. u c CO JD u- O (1) CI TO ■f-J c 0) o 0) a (U XI (U a X c o ■■J 1. O O P>9 O o o OOOOOOOOOOOOLACTvOOOOOLALA r^r-.Ou-\Or--\oo — oLTvuACNiooor^r^c^c^ LTv — — J- — CO a^ oooooooooocoLTic^oooooLALn o^ 1-^ O LA O r'-\ c-\ OLnLAtNo^or-^r^^c"^oJ' — — J- — oo cT* oooooooooo-:tounr^oooooLnLrv LTv — — -3" ■ — r^ CTv ooooocr\OOOLnoupicooooooLr>L-rv fv-vr-. OLnOf^rO' — ocv^Lr^csIrv-^or^^^cNlc^^. — , — \s\ ^- — -:!" — r-^ a■^ ooocooooccriOLPvoooooooLpiuri (v^r^-OLTvO-ct't^ — ocsiLPicsicj^. or^i — c^i>j — . — LA — — J" '- vO CTV OOOOOOOOOi^OUAr^OOCOOLALA fv^^-^OL^^O-:tc^— O — LACM^xiOr^r^t^^icsj^- LA ' — ' — J" ■ — mD cn OOOOOOOOOr-^OLACOOOOOOOLAUA c^. r^ O LA O -X f'A ■ LA • oOLA<>JOOr-r^' — c~^ — ^ — V.O CTi O O O O O O '^ O O r-- O LA O O I"-") O I^^ O LA LA fv', >l O LA O -J- r A — O O 's\ r-A r- O i~^ r^ — i>J ~- O LA O -J- fA — O O lA — — -J- - LA C^ ^ CM CA .J- LA ^ r^ O^ O O — '"^ '-^ "^"^ J" -* ^"^ '•''• '-o ^i) 95 (U -o (U u 0) o (0 > (a 1/1 o > ■«3 1- U c 3 ■M 0) ro vO ro u- O 0) CT (TJ 4-1 c 0) u !_ 0) a 03 "O (D ui 0) 1- a X 0) c o u O o o o LA O o O CNI .— (U "CI -^-» u) < — l_ ^ o rj u (U '71 -o n3 c CQ 13 10 u. r^r^LTvCM— vOJ" w\ rr\ — v£) Lr\J-J"O0 — ltvltvCni cvj rArof»-iJ- CNj i-^cvi rr\ — r»~\oAooLr>o^ur\r^csi CN cvj cm COCO — — r^rsifv~vr-oocMJ-r^ o^ CNI rsl CM vO vO — — LPiCMvOMDo^LAvD — I^ d-r^oOOLnun — CM ' — — c^' — t~~-r^C^f^vOr»^cOroLAr«~vLPvcv-iCNicMrv~i_:j- oar~^ CNicNicMroj-cMro.J- — ^fv-,rv)rsicMur\J- — CM — vOCMCOLAr^a>. & r^ OO CO is\ ir\ — CSI ■ — — — r^csi — r<^Lr\-a-r~-r>-\Lnr^ocM(>jcMf>^_3- POr^ — — CM — CNl rv-(fv-\ — r»~\-d- — Cv-N CM CM CM LTv J- — — ooovo-d-t^LAr^iAvD— J- — ooo^unuTv — cm — — -XiOr^Oror«~>LnOcs;oi~\LrvCMOvX)OsicMo^j- o'^ r-^ O _3- — ur\-d' cmcmpoj- (^r-^OOCMOOCJroo -d" crNoaro. — LA-:i-CMOr^cM CMOOOOOOcM(v-^oOJ- O LPv (V^ -4" — CTWOOO — ro — '^^OvOCMcO — rsl CTvOOCGOOi'v^CnOCAl'^c^cM' — O^OACNIOr-^CM OOOOOOOCMfv~, ooj- C LA OO "^ r^v£) CO vO 1^- ■ — O^ ■ — CX3 ' — CM OOOLAOOn^a^, Or^vDr-^— OlaOCMOcacM OOOOOOOCMCAOOJ- — o O — a LA cv^ — CM fv^. _:f uA -^ r-- ro en o O a E U1 0) 0) . — 1- c It! o o 4-t L) . — o C o 1- — u c m E > O a E a 113 M- o o 0) Q. a) e C 1/1 QJ C o o u LI 1- 1-1 O) (i) ja E fO oooooooooooooj-oooooo ooooooooocnoooooooooo I — CN!J-r--o^,o-;^r•-^^£)0■^' — »x)-J"J"cni — csir^ — r~^ CO LTv un -d" -d" ■ — . — p<-^ CSI , — r^ r^ ^ Lpi -:f 00 CNI CM CO MD CNI — csiLAJ-cNii>-^vo-d"u-\MDc^i"^ — -j-r-cNi— -d"crif^o ■ L-n J- o CM 04 C^ <>■> CnI CO o-i CM — CO r>- <^ -— £> U-\ OOOOOOOOOOOOOCMOOOOOO OOOOOO — OtNIO — 0-d-~r^i0^0000 — LA(>^r^r^o r^upi— cnvococo-d- cmoo cncrir^-t~^ OOCMJ-^|-^vX)J-OvOOOr'-^r--J-v.Di>J — U^OO — i^O LPivrjoD 1^^ — O r 3" ur\0 CTvCJ^f^ r^.J- cm r--> vo CD c c o in o (T\CO u-\ — ^ — — c^ r-^ • — r--- -J- M3 C7^ ^ r^ CT> r^ -cf vo i_n 'j^ -d" CO c^J CNI CO v^ CNI — oa o f.~ o o o o o c o o o o o o o o o o rj o ."5 ■ — CM O or'> CM O ■ — O CM CNI c c^ i'^'^ -cf u-\ vo r-^ ;o CTi o o^ r.-> J- -d^- LA LA vD '.^O J1 c iD E > o E o n CO c o 97 3 c a ZJ (U o CT> c o a E 0) E D C ° ^ ^=5^ O <^^ O O O CT, o o o o o o o o o o o — '- o o o CN! — o en v^ d d d d d d r^-. o_ u•^ vo M 1^ ~ o r^ J- u-N o ^o c-j rv. j^ S ?s [o CTi CO i-a — \o — ' — cr\ cr\ . — 00cvj o a e *^. ^. ^. '^. ^. '^. "^. ^ '^ ° ° *^ '^ '^ CJ <^ o o o o c-J u^ en cv^, cvj" ^' -• „: d u\ ■- oJ o G^ d d d d -' ^- -- >j ."'*\ J" UO '.O I^- OJ C^ O - -\OLriOvDi-rvOOCM — O , — r^ CM — \D — O O O O O o o o r^ CM CX3CMOOOOLA-d-U-\CMOr^OOO\X>OroOOO rs!ooour\Ov£>r~^O^r^f^Ooocr\OrvlO — Or^u-v 0OCTALACMo^r~~vD' — CTitTiO OO' — r^ CM — — r^cM — CT'. — — — (y\ cocMOOOOOocMt>-\OLr\'X)OJ-o-d"000 CMr-oOLAOvO — (T\— OCMcnO — t^ — CM — r^cM — cnc^ — -— CTi — Lr\cv-\CM I — o o cMj- r^MD urvLA-d" r^o cno^' — i^ C0CMJ■CM^^vCO^r)icMOvn-;i"' — <^ f^ . CM — l_-^ r^ CO r^ o cr\ vTi >^ vo O — -cT -:?■ c^J o co cti ^X) r-- ODCMJ-r^i-^MDvnOC^ — vO-^'i-acTvUr^r^-Cj-C — o r-^ O Ln ■ — CO r~- \j^ J- CM r-^ o^, -^o c^> o oj J- lp cm o c^ O^ OO tPi CM vO , — ~ r^ c<~\ — P^J" OUAMD r-'ivD r^ror^- CiO tv^ CM CM LA iT\vO v^ OO — ■ — . — — LT, i->~\ 1^^ r^ o r-. LA — cTi O 00 CXI J- cm .:o CTi C^ p^ ^ 00 -Ml --f \^ r~. vD J" O vj 00 C'^ ^-^ J- CTA tMl — LA O O — r^ O LA MD oo r^ ' — O i^^ -J- LA O j-\ '^ c-j r-^ J- c^J ^v^ vD (J^ CO LA — VD — — c^ c^ ■ — — 1 V.O cn-J- I\ n^ r^ -cr vO CJ CM CS! x> vO CM — ^^ J^ -d' rv-\ — c-J CA 4" LA MD r--- 00 tTi O < en -\ c«-\ ^ CO < ifl < -n -T LA LA vO -O 100 V -o c (0 (D Q. (0 U h en 1_ (U i/i Q. F i_ O fD o U- o *. (3 CM ^— ■IJ- 0) J -a • — 1 _ (U ra ^— < o o c -d- o •u- LO en CL c o •— l_ -— O n: D 1/1 cr 3 0) o ■— j-i v_ .« TO -o > D 1_ y- U O nj to !_ -o -t-» 3 X Q. 0) XJ 3 -o o c fil t£ u Ul (U 4-1 H- C , — TO m u t ■(-> .— 1/; ■M c Q. o O (J • o 4- C O TO O <4- TO o o o o o o O J- O — o CM r-~ O O — ro O O CNI LPl VT) LA O r-^ — c-J 00 O en — CNI CX3 oo J- O rv^ a> r^ 00 O^ -d" ^ o^ CNI vo u^ (TV O o a^ LA CO CNI — 00 LA o r^ OA CA o o^ O O t^ CD O kO 00 CA \o CM ,— o o o O MD CNI vX) OA o CO 1^ CO CO 00 r-~ o^ J- r~~. o CA LA — O r-- \£) — t>-\ -j- '— r~^ O CNi vX) O — CTi CNI CO (X) OG -:r O CO CNI — VD O en CA vD 00 CNI LA CNI CNI J- LP oA o^ o o o o r~- ' — cNi cr\-d- >J3 cr. 00 vo — 00 r-~ CNJ — o o o o o o CNJ csj O CNI CNI (^ 0) o o 0) o CD .1) o o o o ^ in o o l/l t-j o l/l o o u-j o o 4-1 TO ^ o TO -J" o TO -:r o TO -J- o ' — CQ * lC * ra - irc U CNI CNl CM CM 0) ■<.>■ -CJ. \i- ■o- ■u. -ei %> -u- !_ tj O^ CT. (T> O O O 101 of strawberries, torratoes and sweetpotatoes on each of the four farms studied from Alajuela. Intermediate effects of lesser increases of credit v-jere an expansion of sugarcane and a decrease in limes. Dps and downs in production occurred with sugarcane and sweetpotatoes as credit was increased. Sugarcane and tomatoes first replaced coffee and then higher increases in credit allowed strawberries and svjeet- potatoes to be expanded as labor supervision became a limiting factor in certain months. This pattern v\ias not the case on farm 11 because a lower labor supervision constraint vjas programmed. In that case, labor supervision blocked expansion of intensive horticultural crops before coffee output was affected. Those crops giving higher net returns per manzana than coffee required higher levels of labor as well as more short-run capital than v-^as required for coffee production. As shown in Table 21, the Increase of credit availability also allowed intensive horticultural crops to substitute for coffee. Small increases in credit Increased coffee output on the two farms which had the most land not planted to coffee and for which semi -abandoned coffee was part of the initial optimal solution. Coffee output was reduced to zero before labor supervisory restraints blocked the production of blackberri es. Subsidies for Alternatives The payment of subsidies for the production of specific alter- natives is also a possible policy measure, in general, results in- dicated that this was less efficient than disincentives for coffee production when the same resuHs \-:ere obtainable. Subsidies for black- berries or s tra'wberries had no effect on coffee acreage In those situa- tions where part of the farm v/as not pI-Dnted to coffee. Credit limited 02 Table 21, Optima] output of various crops on Acosta farms v/ith high fruit price? given base capita] and credit and extra credit equaling .^i+OO and ^^2,000 per manzana Farm Credi t/mz. Coffee (faneqas) Limes (qui ntales) Blackberries (qui ntales) 13A 13A ]3A Base t ^+00 ^2,000 195.6 162.5 0 17,780 20,644 36,607 0 0 1,402 ]k/\ Base i 400 .;2,00C 18.4 22.8 0 3,600 4,175 5,695 0 0 294 15A 15A ISA Base els of change are given. N'ever the 1 ess , the com- parative costs indicate that the cheapest i-pethod or controlling coffee output woiild be carried out with resource re^! 1 ^ocet i on after some direct control of output. An annual subsidy for coffee tree removal gives slightly higher removal costs on two of the farms v.'hich indi- cates that other factors are ri-)ore easily shifted out of coffee 120 Table 35. "he comparative costs of various methods of reducing coffee output on farm 9 Coffee reduction Method Cost per faneqa Fanegas Percent Burning coffee Credit reduction (10%) Credit reduction {207o) Credit reduction (30%) Credit reduction (50%) Credit reduction (70%) Subsidize oranges (c;3.98/100) Subsidize limes (^.6.37/qq.) Subsidize limes (<;b7.95/qq. ) Coffee tree removal Coffee tree removal Coffee tree removal Coffee tree removal Mandatory abandonment Mandatory serri -abarioonment Mandatory traditional output Resource reallocation Resource reallocation Resourc3 reallocation Resource reallocation ^196.73 997.2 100.0 109.96 62.2 6.2 110.92 126.6 12.7 112.49 195.2 19.6 113.69 332.5 33.3 116.96 512.0 51.3 99.01 709.5 71.2 63.46 259.9 26.1 67.26 666.6 66.8 43.54 171.5 17.2 43.91 180.7 18.1 51.92 309.7 31.1 67.00 454,8 45.6 117.90 25.0 2.5 114.63 21,0 2.1 119.52 16.0 1.6 43.39 176.2 17.7 43.67 183. 9 18.4 49.51 317.2 31.8 54.31 452.0 45.3 Calculated by shifting one manzana from hiohest technology to a lower level of output holding otner production constant. 121 Table 36. The comparative costs of various methods of reducing coffee output on farm 10 ■ Coffee reduction Method Cost per faneqa Faneqas Percent Burninq coffee a Mandatory abandonment Mandatory semi -abandonment Mandatory traditional output Subs Subs Subs Subs Subs Subs Subs Subs Subs dize pineapples (^Il4.91/T.) dize pineapples (cl56.45/T.) dize oranges (c'1.96/100) dize oranges ((jif.98/] 00) dize strawberries (:o\'Cz limited. When credit was incredsed, strawoerry, sweetpotato and tomato production i.'-.creased. When credit vjas re-Juced severely, semi -abandoned ]k2 coffee and traditional crops of corn and beans became the most profit- able acti vi ties. The expansion of horticultural crops depends upon stable high prices for industrial use. Fresh fruit and vegetables for the domestic market receive much higher prices but also face considerable risk. These combinations of high average prices and high risks have checked modernization of technology. Conservative management policy cuts in- put cost to minimi i-e loss in years of low prices or at least to hold risks to some acceptable level. This Interplay of risks and profits in dfcci sion-inaki ng processes cause actual resource use to deviate from long-run profit maxi mi zaci on. An additional factor of small market size also afreets decision making. Each of a few producers may be able to influence price; therefore, the high domestic price levels were not used in the analysis of fruit and vegetable alternatives. Opposition to policies favoring the industrialization of horticultural p.'oducLs may be expected from fruit and vegetable producers currently serving the fresh produce market. In Acosta, high fruit prices brought large shifts in resources from cofF»">e to limes. Blackberries could be encouraged by incr-2?Ged credit in addition to stable high industrial prices. Additicr.a! changes to be brought about by other policy .reasures would be slew to occur and relatively unimportant. '/hen low fruit prices vjere used in the annlysis,. coffee was replaced by corn and beans vji ch niode ra ta! y smdll declines in the coffee price. Poor yielding coffee could be removed by trixarion or market price declines. But the short-run best allocation of resources would be disastrous over a long time period. The topoqraphy is rough 143 and unsuited to rev.' crops. Erosion and leaching of soils exposed to heavy rains would bring e continuing decline of productivity to farms i n the Acosta area. Comparative Costs of Coffee Removal The costs of reducing optimal coffee output using various policy measures were calculoted for 20 farm situations, 'wide differences occurred from farm to farm and among methods. In general, low-yielding coffee was cheaper to remove than high- yielding coffee. However, the costs of coffee reduction increased as the quantity reduced on a particular farm increased. The productivity of the alternatives also entered into the costs of reducing coffee output. For examp'r-, It was cheaper to remove 25 fanegas per manzana of coffee from an Alajuela farm with horticultural crops among its alternatives than to remove 19 fanegas per manzana of coffee from a farm in Palmares with poor-er alternative possibilities. Credit re- strictions on poorer farms blocked higher return alternatives and raised the comparative costs of reducing coffee above the costs of reducing better yielding coffee en more profitable farms. Small re- ductions in coffee oij'put were made most cheaply on a^^eraae or lower yielding farms. However, when larger reductions in coffee output required destruction of coffee trees, the credit constraint caused the costs to incre^ise more rapidly on those lower yielding farnis v^hich also had less operating capital per manzana. Vihen coffee tree rertioval v/as programmed as the means to reduce coffee output, highest costs v.erie as --oci a ted wi ch the poorest farms. V.'ith the exceptions of the poorest farm:;, the costs of removing trees that produced one fanega of coffee from production vjere below the costs of burning coffee after it had been produced. Generally, costs ranged upward from ^1^ per fanega and were clustered below ^llOO. Re- ducing inputs to coffee, as a means of reducing output, can be expected to cost C75 to i:\2S per fanega when inputs are not reallocated to other uses. Credit reductions sometimes reduced the production of other crops. \lhen this occurred, credit reductions v;ere an extremely expensive vjay of reducing coffee output. Costs ranged from ^75 to over (^2,000 per fanega of reduction in coffee output. Blocking new plantings reduced optimal coffee output slightly on two farms. A tax or injunction against new plantifigs would not greatly reduce potential incomes with present price relationships. Potential Effects of Technological Advances in Coffee Production The iTiajor threat to the acceptance of a program of crop diversi- fication is tliat technological changes in coffee prcduc*"ion v\il! be easier to initiate than more complex changes in I'arm munagement vjhich shift resources out of coffee, Fiirthermoce , given present prices, tho returns to modernized coffee production surpass leturns to alternatives that compete with coffee fo-- tlie allocation of crrront resources on most farms. Many fr'.rms would dojbie net incomes and expand coffee production if rnoie productive cof fee-gro-.M ng activities could be criployed. Even with prices or yields lovjei'cd 20 percent, the majority of I'm farms studied would increase net Incoire, by adopting nev< coffee technoloqy. The increased coffee output expected from technological change ■.•/ould orfset reducti or.s expected from d i versi f i ca t I'.)n of curi'ent 1^5 resources. The costs of reallocating resources to reduce coffee out- put will be increased by advances in coffee production technology. The programmed incomes on seven out of eight farms with fruit or vegetable alternatives vjere higher when credit was increased than v,'hen coff?e technology was changed. Therefore, if production of coffee is to be held in check by voluntary means, large increases in the supply of credit for horticultural crops must be made along with investments for processing plants and extension programs. Involuntary production controls using farm quotas is another v/ay of checking the potential expans ion. The Q^ual i fi cations of an Acceptable Alternative In a study of this nature, all possible crops cannot be included because of time and cost restrictions. However, from the crops studied, certain patterns were indicated. An alternative must net higher returns per maoiiana than coffee if it is to cause coffee trees to be destroyed and the land planted to another crop. The diffc'^ence .Tust be high enough to pay for coffee tree removal. Smaller downward adjustments in coffee production can occur when an alternative is superior to other non-coFfec crops and cciipetcs with coffee for non-land resources. One may expect such changes to be temporary since over time increased income may al'Cw purchases of addi t ; onal i npu ts. Before intensive, horticultural crops replace significant quan- tities of coffee, add'tionai credit is required. Or. most coffee farms, labor does not appear to ba a critif;ally limiting factor o'' production, Fierefoie, an acceptable alternative may use m.ore hour-wage labor than coffee. l/f6 Finally, the alternative crop must face a stable price. Profit maximization is a rational alternative only after risk against loss is held to an acceptable level. Despite dovjnvjard trends over the past few years, coffee prices in comparison with alternatives have been reasonably stable. Diversification Versus Production Control Crop diversification and coffee production control are not Iden- tical. Diversification can be rationally expanded In coffee growing regions. Diversification Is a relative rather than an absolute concept. The benefits of risk reduction, income increases and tax-base expansion occur vjhen the production of other crops is expanded whether or not coffee output is red;jced. This analysis shovjs that some opportunity for crop divp.rs I fi cation does exist. However, the projections of resijl ts of farm case studies to broader generalizations do not j-jstlfy optimisiT; that crop diversification can effectively control coffee out- put. Moreover, other factors Influence decision making In addition to annuoi net Income incentives. The higher lev^i of risk and the need for closer supervision may block certain activities even when requirements for new tecnnlcal knowledge are supplied. Credit reduction can limit coffee production without aiding diver- si ^I c."i '. i c i and rX. cerate crp,diL e^-.p^juslon csn e \ i dl vers I "^i ca tion vnth- out limiting coffee output. Piofitcbie di vers! f Icatl':'--! al rr^rna t i ves icv;er the opportunity cost associated vjith Involuntary reductl r ns of coffee output. In comparison with the destruction of h'-'j r vested coffee, the reallocation of resources to alternative usss is niurh cheaper as a means of controlling national )k7 coffee sales. Likewise a program of quotas , payment for coffee tree removal, subsidies to alternative crops, or se'ective credit allocation probably would rnak3 diversification more acceptable to farmers. GLOSSARY ] bottle (botelle) = I.5 pounds of milk = 0.6/ liters 1 colon = SO. 150^ (official rate: ^1.00 = ib.SS) ] fanega = ^Lq to 56O pounds of coffee = 400 liters cherries or 10^+ pounds of coffee beans- 1 raanzana = 1.727 acres :z: 0,698896 hectares ] metric ton . = 2,2Qi+.6 pounds = \CQC kilograms 1 quintal ^ 100 pounds (Spanish) = kb kilograms or 101 .'+ pounds (Engl i sh) 1^(8 APPENDIX 150 Introduction to the Appendix The input and output coefficients used in this analysis are in- cluded in the Appendix. Changes in technology will undoubtedly alter yields and both quantity and quality of inputs used. The results and conclusions reached in this study will hold only as long as the yield and input coefficients are representative of existing relationships. The following units of measure apply to the data in the appendix tables. All labor, labor supervision and family harvest labor were re- corded in hours. The monetary unit Is the colon ((;t6.65 = $1,G0), The er:tries in the investment rows were made in units of 100 colones. The other monetary items are in units of one colon. Land entries are in unil:s of one manzana. Monthly entries were comibined in the appendix tables with the first and last '-i-onths c'otsig' nate.d. Oui:put c.':ef f icients varied from crop to crop. The ,nost corinion unit, the qji;-it.:;i ({00 Spanish pounds), vjas used for the fol lov,'ing crops: corn, beans, swee Lpo ta toes , cassava, buckwheat, pigson peas, chickpeas, limes, cobacco, si rav^'berr i^s and blackberries. Metric ton v.'as used as the unit oT pj"od>,ic t i on for sugc"~rc3nc, tcinatoes and pp.ppers Banc-'na output v/as entered in units of 1 JO stems and crsngc output v.v's enter-cd in units cf 100 fruits., Milk output i-.a;i entered in units of 100 Dottles (!,5 pounds each). in a number of ths appendix tables monlhs o-' Labor wer^'i cn'il ttod v,'[-.en no i.^bor was required. Also, in order to conserve space, one or more digits to the right of the. decimal ^ as used in the proof animi ng ?":a]yscs, v;ere oniit,.rrd in tlie ci;j|Kn(iix t^b'cs. 151 Coefficients for coffee producing activities 1 through 5, Palmares- San Ramon Acti vi ty I tern 1 2 3 k 5 Prof i t -620.00 -633.55 -6^5.25 -553.05 -1,^86.75 January labor 0 0 1.00 0 0 March labor 2^.00 18.00 50.00 36.00 132.00 Apri 1 labor 50.00 29.00 28.00 0 100.00 May Ubor 103.00 31.00 32.00 12.00 152.00 June labor 23.00 22.00 35.00 66.00 80.00 July labor 15.00 23.00 5.00 ^8.00 18.00 August labor hS . 00 13.00 28.00 30.00 88.00 September labor 20.00 13.00 0 72.00 8^^.00 October labor 6'+. 00 9.00 0 0 128.00 November labor 0 0 1.00 60.00 0 1 rsvestment 13.00^ 12.80"^ 7.^5*^ 0 0 Operati ng capi ta 1 if51.00 A.67.85 509.50 ^^38. 00 i ,23'4.00 Rotation, castorbeans 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 Rotation, beans 1,00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 Land, all year 1,00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1 . CO Coffee land maximum 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 Coffee land minimum. 1.00, - 27. 60^^ 1.00 - 25.70'' 1.00 1.00 1.00 Yield transfer ~ 19.00 - 15.00 20.00 Yield change 27.60 25.70 19.00 15.00 20.00 ^This activity v.'as blocked on Farms 3 "Snd 'f. This entry of investment in hundreds of colones vvas not used on Farms 1 and 2 vjhere the investment had already been made. ''Tins investpient entry was used only for Farms 3 ^'^nd 4. !n this activity, yield v.as placed directly into the coffee transfer row only in Farms 1 ai-d 2. Parame cr i c prog.-emmi ng procedures a!]o'-.ed this activity to be considered on Farms 3 through 8. 152 Coefficients for cof San Ramon fee p'-oducing activities 6 through 10, Palmares- Act i vi ty 1 tem 6^ 7 8 9 10 Profit -if82.i+0 -156.25 -770.00 -20.00 -375.00 January labor 0 c 0 0 0 February labor 0 0 0 0 0 March labor 36.00 60.00 132.00 0 60.00 Apri 1 labor 20.00 60.00 15.00 20.00 30.00 May labor 37.00 75.00 0 0 18.00 June labor 12.00 75.00 48.00 0 6.00 July labor 31.00 35.00 36.00 0 0 August labor 12.00 50.00 24.00 45.30 16.00 September labor 0 50.00 36.00 '45.00 30.00 October labor 7.00 0 0 0 0 November labor 0 0 0 0 0 December labor 0 0 0 0 0 ! nvestment 0 0 0 0 0 Operati ng capi tal /405.00 103.00 66ii,00 0 322.70 Rci;atiori, castorbeans 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 l.CO Rotation, becns 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 l.GO Land, all year 1.00 1 ,00 1.00 1.00 1.00 Coffee land maximum ! . 00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 Coffee land minin'um 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 Yield transfer ' 15. CO ~ 5,0c - 15.00 - i+.OO - 5.30 Yield change 15.00 5.00 15.00 h.OQ 5.30 a-^ his activity v;es !) locked or- Farms 3 '^nd ^. 153 Coefficients for flue-cured tobacco producing activities, Palmares- San Ramon Acti vi ty 1 tern 1 2 3 Prof! t -2,617.70 -2 ,32'+. 80 -2,785.70 Labor: January 377.00 200.00 125.00 February 59.00 277.00 0 March 0 120.00 0 June 30.00 0 0 July 260,00 0 180.00 August 115.00 2^8.00 69.00 Septenbar 230.00 118.00 153. CO October 159.00 30.00 93.00 November 315.00 0 22.00 December 510.00 0 137.00 Land: June-January 1.00 0 0 Jul y-Jenuary 0 0 1.00 August -Jr.nuary 0 1.00 0 1 nvestment 20.00 20.00 20.00 Ope rati ng capi tal 2,if30.95 1, ,231.00 2,703.30 Flue-cure^-l contract 1.00 l.CO 1.00 Tobacco transfer, flue 20.00 17.60 18.80 15^ Coef f i cients San Ramrfn for hurley tobacco producing activities, Palmares- Act! vi ty 1 ten 1 2 3 Prof i t -1,4^+7.10 -1 ,105.10 -1,293.70 January labor 675.00 l'i6.00 300,00 February labor 20,00 0 0 July labor 33.00 0 0 August labor 25if.OO 180.00 180,00 Septeinber labor 19^+. 00 127.00 123.00 October labor iflZ.OO 79.00 183.00 November labor 209.00 192,00 126.00 Oscember labor 462.00 1^6. 00 108.00 Land, August through December 1.00 1,00 1.00 Opera ti ng capi tal 1 ,289.00 ],0i+5.00 1 ,238.00 Burley contract 1.00 1.00 1.00 Tobacco transfer, bur ley 18.00 18,00 23.00 155 Coefficients of sun-cured tobacco producing activities, Palmares- San Ramon Act i vi ty tem .1 Profit Labor: January February March July August September October November December Land: August-December Sapte~har- January Cperati ng capi ta] Sun-cured contract Tobacco transfer, sun -1,031.^0 -757.95 -I ,028.80 0 210.00 0 589.0 200.00 210.00 68.00 0 M+.oo 0 17 2,00 0 20^.00 153.00 126.00 59.00 156.00 72.00 137.00 57.00 168.00 98.00 320.00 0 186.00 l.GC 0 1.00 0 1.00 0 905.00 709.10 970.00 1,00 1.00 1.00 13,00 - 19.00 20.00 156 Coefficients of corn producing activities San Ramon 1 through k. Palmares- Act! vi ty I tern 1 2 3 k Profit -^+84.50 -ksk.so -352.15 -352.15 Labor: January 90„00 0 66.00 0 April 172.00 172.00 72.00 72.00 May 90.00 90.00 72.00 72.00 June 98.00 98.00 66.00 66.00 July - 18.00 18.00 ^.00 k.QO August 18.00 18., 00 '+. 00 '4.00 September 0 0 18.00 0 October 0 90,00 0 66.00 Land: Apri l-January 1.00 0 0 0 Apri 1-Octcber 0 1.00 0 1.00 i>1arch-January 0 0 1.00 0 Oparati ng capi tal 351.^0 351.^0 259.^0 259.40 Corn shel 1 i ng - 69.09 - 70.00 - ^8.00 ~ i+9.00 Corn transfer - 69.00 - 70.00 - L8.00 - ^9.00 Special credit -351. '40 -351. i^O - 259 . '^0 -259.^0 157 Coefficients of corn producing activities 5 through 8, Palmares- San Ramon Acti v' '_ty 1 ten 5 6 7 8 Profit -156.50 -102.85 -142.95 -142.95 • Labor: January 0 0 0 60.00 March 8i+,00 i+8.00 0 0 Apri 1 0 0 19.00 19.00 May 66.00 8.00 24.00 24 . 00 June 5^.00 56.00 41.00 4i.00 July 18.00 0 2.00 2.00 September 0 0 0 10.00 October 66.00 18.00 30.00 0 November 0 18.00 0 0 Land: March-October 1.00 0 0 0 March- November 0 1.00 0 0 April-July^ 0 0 1.00 1.00 Operati ng capi tal 95.00 71.00 n 3 . 40 113.40 Corn she] 1 i ng - ^0.00 - 2i+.00 - 13.00 - 13.00 Corn transfer - '40.00 - 2'+,C0 ~ 13.00 - 13.00 Special credit " 95.00 - 71.00 -113.40 - 1 i 3 . 40 ax rhinly planted corn allows another crop to be planted after July. 158 Coefficients of corn-bean producing activities 1 through 4, Palmares- San Ramon Act i vi ty 1 tern 1 2 3 4 Profit -4^7.50 -251.95 -163.00 -162.10 Labor: January 5^.00 0 0 60.00 March 0 8i+.00 0 48.00 Apri 1 72.00 0 19.00 0 May 72.00 102.00 0 56.00 June 66.00 86.00 53.00 68.00 July i+.OO 18.00 2.00 12.00 August i+.OO 66.00 72.00 72.00 September 18.00 44.00 66.00 66.00 October 152.00 60,00 20.00 20.00 November 60.00 0 20,00 20.00 December 0 0 0 20.00 Land: March-January 1.00 0 0 0 March-October 0 1,00 0 March-August^ 0 0 1.00 0 Apri 1-August^ 0 0 0 i.OO Operati ng capi tal 353.80 113.70 129.60 89.00 Rotation, beans 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 Corn shel 1 ing - ifS.oo - 40.00 - 13.00 - 24.00 Corn transfer - '48.00 - 40.00 - 13.00 - 24. CO Bean transfer - 9.60 - 4.00 - 5.40 - 5.40 Special credi t -353.. 80 "113.70 -129.60 - 89.00 After bean harvest the thinly planted corn allov/ed another crop to be planted. 159 Coefficients for bean producing activities 1 through k, Palinares- San Ramon Act i vi ty 1 tern 1 2 3 h Profit -396.95 -289.85 -116.10 - 62.10 Labor: January 57.00 0 60.00 60.00 February 0 0 0 28.00 Apr] 1 0 280.00 0 0 May 0 90.00 0 0 June 0 98.00 0 0 July 0 57.00 0 0 August 2^0.00 18.00 0 0 September 92.00 ^+7.00 0 0 October 51.00 108.00 80.00 22.00 November 12.00 0 60.00 0 December '47.00 0 0 0 Land: September- January 1.00 0 0 0 October-January 0 0 1.00 0 October- February 0 0 0 1,00 Apri 1-Septenber 0 1.00 0 0 Operati ng cap! tal 352.35 261,35 9^4.^0 51.70 Rotation, beans l.CO l.GO l.OG 1.00 Bean transfer - 20.00 - 18.00 - 9.50 - 'i. 20 Special credit -352.35 -261.35 - 9^.'^0 - 5i.70 160 Coefficients for sesame and castorbean producing activities, Palmares- San Raron Sesame Castorb 1 lean I tem 1 2 1 2 Profit -267.90 -36,25 -i+50.85 -268.ii5 Labor: January 120.00 80.00 0 0 February 110.00 36.00 0 0 April 0 0 72.00 72.00 May 0 0 22.00 78.00 June 0 0 3.00 60.00 July 0 0 15.00 5^.00 September 0 72.00 0 0 October 272.00 88,00 90.00 90,00 November ^.00 36,00 120,00 100,00 Land: Sept ember- January 0 1. 00 0 0 October-January 1.00 0 0 0 Apri l~October 0 0 1.00 1,00 Operati ng capi tal 228.75 19.00 370.25 203.70 Rotation, castorbean 0 0 5.00 5.00 Sesame transfer - 20.00 -11,00 0 0 Castorbean transfer 0 0 - 34.00 - 32.00 Special credit -228.75 -19.00 -370.25 -203.70 161 Coefficients for dairy activities, Palmares-San Ramon Actl vl ties 1 tern 1 2 3 k 5 Profit -476.9 -68.7 -63.0 -467.2 -188.2 Labor: January 20.0 15.0 15.0 10.0 10.0 February 20.0 15.0 15.0 10.0 10.0 March 20.0 15.0 15.0 10. 0 10.0 Apri ] 20.0 15.0 15.0 10.0 10.0 May 20.0 15.0 15.0 10.0 10.0 June 27.0 15.0 15.0 17.0 17.0 July 2'+,0 29.0 35.0 10.0 10.0 August 2i+.0 23,0 35.0 14.0 14.0 September 2i+.0 15.0 35.0 10.0 10.0 October 24.0 15.0 15.0 10.0 10.0 November 20.0 15.0 15.0 10.0 10.0 December 20.0 15.0 15.0 10.0 10.0 Land ^ 2.5 2.5 5.0 1.0 1.0 Opera ti ng cap! tal 2,286.9 608.7 603.0 1 ,277.2 977.2 PxOtation, castorbeans 2.5 2.5 5.0 I.O 1.0 Rotation, bears 2.5 2.5 5.0 1.0 1.0 1 r.ves tmcr.t 19.0 6.0 6.0 9.0 9.0 Milk transfer - 30.0 -10.0 -10.0 - 20.0 - 10.0 Cajf transfer 0 - 0.9 - 0.8 - 0.9 - 0.8 Special credi t -2.235.9 -603.7 -603.0 -1 ,277.2 -977.2 162 Coefficients for beef and pigeon pea and mixed crop producing activities, Pa!mares-San Ramon Beef Pi geon ■ ■ ■ Mixed 1 tem 1 2 pea crop Prof i t -1^+2.00 - 63.00 -308.90 -i+78,20 Labor: January 5.00 1.00 6.00 5.00 February 5.00 1.00 6.00 86,00 Karch 5.00 1,00 160.00 120, CO Apri 1 5.00 1.00 2t+0,00 2^+0.00 Kay 5.00 1.00 (70.00 170.00 June 13.00 3^.00 40.00 7^.00 July 13.00 3^.00 0 12.00 August 13.00 3'+.oo 6.00 6.00 Sepcember 5.00 1.00 6.00 118.00 October 5.00 1.00 2i+0.00 140.00 November 6.00 2.00 0 160.00 December 5.00 1.00 0 22.00 Land, all year 1.50 5.00 1.00 1,00 Operati ng cepi ta] 862.00 603.00 272.00 386.20 1 n vestment 8.00 6.00 0 0 Rotation, castorbeans 1.50 5.00 0 0 Rotation, beans 1.50 5.00 - 1.00 1.00 Calf transfer - 0.75 ~ 0.50 0 0 Pigeon pea transfer 0 0 - 20.00 - 13.00 Corn transfer 0 0 0 ~ 30.00 Bean transfer 0 0 0 - 4.80 Chickpea transfer 0 0 0 - •'+. 00 Special credi t -C62.00 "603.00 -272.00 -3S6.00 163 Coefficients fcr peanut, chickpea and buckwheat producing activities, Palmares-San Ramon Peanut Chickpea Buckv/n leat 1 tern 1 2 Prof i t -362.0 -82.6 -105.7 - 56.8 Labor: January 0 66.0 180.0 12.0 February 0 20.0 0 0 March 0 0 0 120.0 August kkl.O 0 0 0 September kS.O 0 0 0 October 12,0 22.0 0 0 Moven'iber 72.0 0 12.0 0 Land: August-November 1,0 0 0 0 October- February 0 1.0 0 0 November- January 0 0 1.0 0 January-March 0 0 0 1.0 Operati ng caoi ta] 312.0 77.2 72.5 ko.k Peanut transfer - 20.0 0 0 0 B'-Jckvjheat transfer 0 0 - 20.0 - 8.0 Chickpea transfer 0 - 5.0 0 0 Special credi t -312.0 -77.2 - 72.5 -hO.k ]6k Coffee picking activities, all areas tem Profit Labor: January February November DeceiTiber CoT^fee picking activity January February November December 1.0 1.0 1.0 1.0 1.0 0 0 1.0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1.0 0 0 0 0 1.0 ^An additional picking activity for October coffee picking is included elsewhere for the Acosta area. 165 Coefficients for coffee harvesting and corn shelling operations, Palmares-San Ramon Coffee Hired harvesting Fami ly Corn she 1 1 i nq I tern Hand labor Contract Profi t -i+O.OO 0 0 -1.00 All labor: January 0.50 5.00 2. 50 0 February 0.50 i+.OO 0 0 November 0.50 4.00 0 0 December 0.50 5.00 0 0 Fami ly labor only: January 0 5.00 0 0 February 0 i+.OO 0 0 November 0 i+,00 0 0 December 0 5.00 0 0 Coffee harvest 1.00 !.00 0 0 Corn shel 1 i ng 0 0 1. 00 1.00 166 o a > c 13 c -1 !_ (~ a) c •_ 3 o -3 en < -— OOOOOOOOOOO OOOCOOOOOOO — — oooooooooo — o— oooooooooo — o — ooooooooo — oo oo I ooooooooo — oo '— oooooooo — ooo— oooooooo — ooo ooooooo — oooo— ooooooo — oooo cv^ O ra O — OOOOOO — OOOOO— OOOOOO — OOOOO O o-\ O OOOOO — OOOOOO— OOOOO — OOOOOO — oooo — OOOOOOO— OOOO — OOOOOOO O c^ OOO — O OOOOOOO — o O C.'J — o o o o o o o o o O ro — oooooooooo • - ooo — oooo oooo oo — oooo OOOOO O •- O O O O C OOOOO i>^ O r~\ O — -OOOCOOOOOOO— —OOOOOOOOOOO a L. m •• L. '_,-^ 'jj l. *™ (J c ■>^ (U u '- >- i_ J3 1. ■.:.) Cj O >- L Ji 1_ 0) o l_ f" J J E C*j J.: J CJ) — 1- m jj c: (U ~ /^ '0 :5 _c — i/i 'U .-\ i= E C 1/1 TO -■3 -IT - — U1 Z^ X) 6 "ir n; i- o .-. o >- 3 +-J "o ■ii OJ .— ..- 3 u O y >> 3 .o c (U CJ -VJ . • c 'i v^ 'i_ ">* i: — CTl Q- ^ u -^-' > c -Q u L >- c 1 — cr» D. -l-J > O .-.- L 'C cij ■t) Q. 03 3 3 -J c; t> o I'J .■D '• Q TJ m a. m 3 3 3 C.) 'J c !> U- o -> u. -4^ < 2: "") -? < O) o ."SI o V- (U -3 U_ TT < ?: -> "5 < O") o :?: Q O o a; a. I- •^ o. n: Q. _J o 167 Coefficients for borrowing, planting coffee, destroying coffee, and fixed costs transfer activities, all areas Act i vi ties Plant Destroy Transfer 1 terr, Borrow coffee coffee fixed costs Profit -6.0 - 300.0 - 60.0 -100.0 ! n vestment -1.0 lOi+.O 6.0 0 Interest change -1.0 0 0 0 Operati ng capi tal 0 2,108.i; 600.0 0 Coffee land maximum 0 1.0 1.0 0 Coffee land minimum 0 0 - 1.0 0 Existing coffee 0 0 1.0 0 Removal payment 0 -9,999.0 1.0 0 Fixed expenditures 0 0 0 1.0 168 Coefficients for moving family v/orkers and permanent employees to off- farm employment, all areas Labor movement activities tern All labor: January February March Aori 1 Kay June July August Saptember October November December Fami ly I abor: January February Ncvemba r December Supe rvi s i on: January February March Apri i May June July August September Oc tobe r tsoveir.ber December pcimi 1 y rnsn Men employed Off- farm pay Reduced labor'^ Reduced Icbor cost (^costa) Fami ly Employees 156.0 156.0 \kk.0 \kk.0 162,0 162.0 150.0 150.0 162.0 162.0 156.0 156.0 16 2.0 162.0 150.0 150.0 150.0 150.0 162,0 162.0 150.0 150.0 120.0 120.0 156.0 0 ]kk.O 0 150.0 0 120.0 0 312.0 312.0 288.0 288.0 32i+.0 324.0 300.0 300.0 32'+.0 32'i.O 312.0 312.0 32J+.0 324.0 300.0 300,0 300.0 300.0 32'i.0 3 2'+.0 300.0 300.0 2'; 0.0 240.0 1.0 0 0 1.0 3,116,0 0 0 2,208.0 0 1,520.0 All other areas except Acosta, 169 Coefficients of ri ght-hand-i I de constraints, farms ] through k, Palmares-San Ramon Farms J tern 1 2 3 4 Labor: January 936.00 1,560.0 1 , 404.0 1,560.0 February 86'+. 0 1 ,440,0 1,296,0 1 ,440.0 March 580.0 1.390,0 1,458,0 1 ,066.0 April 5 -'+0.0 1 ,290.0 1,350.0 1,990.0 May 580.0 1.390.0 1,458.0 1 ,066.0 June 560.0 1,340.0 1 ,404.0 1 ,058.0 July 580.0 1.390.0 1 ,458.0 1 .066.0 August 5^0.0 1,290,0 1,350.0 990.0 September 5^0.0 1 ,290.0 1,350.0 990.0 October 580.0 1,390.0 1,458.0 1 ,066.0 November 735.0 1,390.0 1,350.0 1,360.0 December 720.0 1 ,200.0 1 ,080.0 1 ,200.0 Land, each month 5.0 7.0 56.0 20,0 Ope rati ng capi tal ^, 400.0 4,000.0 71 ,100.0 16,900.0 Burley contract 2,0 0 0 0 Flue-cured contract 0 0 3.0 5.0 Rotation, castorbeans 5.0 7.0 56.0 20,0 Rotation, beans 5.0 7.0 56.0 20.0 Harvest labor: January 624.0 624.0 0 1.348.0 February 576.0 576.0 0 ',252.0 November 435.0 390.0 0 1 ,090,0 December ^80.0 480.0 0 960,0 Supervi si on: January 624.0 2,184.0 4,680.0 1 ,560,0 February 576.0 2,016.0 4,320,0 1 ,440,0 March 643,0 2,268.0 4,860.0 1 ,620.0 Apri 1 600.0 2,100.0 4,500.0 1 ,500,0 May 648.0 2,268.0 4,850.0 1 ,620.0 June 624.0 2,184.0 4,680,0 i ,560.0 July 548.0 2,268.0 4,860.0 ] ,620.0 August 600,0 2, i 00.0 4,500.0 1 ,500,0 September 600.0 2.100,0 4,500.0 i ,500.0 October 648.0 2,268.0 'S 860.0 1 ,62C.O November 500.0 2,100.0 4,500.0 1 ,500.0 December 480.0 1 ,680.0 3,600.0 i ,200.0 Fixed expenditures 61.8 166.9 601. .0 143.4 Coffee land maximum 3.0 7.0 50.0 15.0 Coffee land minimum 3.0 7.0 50.0 15.0 F.xi sti ng coffee 3.0 7.0 50.0 15.0 Fcmi ]y men i,0 2.0 0 3.0 Han employed ?.o 5.0 3.0 3.0 Al lot.TV'.nt of quota 62.2 135.0 562.5 16S.7 170 Coefficients of right-hand-side constraints, farms 5 through 8, Pal ma res- San Ramon Farms 1 tern 5 6 7 8 Labor: January 62'+.0 624.0 312.0 624.0 February 576.0 576.0 288.0 576.0 March 6i+8.0 648.0 162.0 418.0 April 600.0 600.0 150.0 390.0 May 648.0 648.0 162,0 413.0 June 624.0 624.0 156.0 404.0 July 6^48.0 648.0 162.0 418.0 August 600.0 600.0 150.0 390.0 September 600.0 600.0 150.0 390.0 October 648,0 648.0 162.0 418.0 November 600.0 600,0 300.0 490.0 December 480.0 480.0 240.0 480.0 Land 10.0 4.0 6.0 2.0 Operati ng capi tal 6,400.0 4,000.0 4,300.0 900.0 Sun-cured contract 0 0 1.0 0.5 Rotation, castcrbeans 10.0 4.0 6.0 2.0 Rotation, beans 10.0 4,0 6.0 2.0 Harvest labor: January 312.0 0 156.0 624.0 February 288.0 0 144.0 576.0 November 300.0 0 150.0 340.0 December 240.0 0 120.0 360.0 Supervi si on: January 1,248.0 1 ,248.0 624.0 624.C February 1,152.0 1,152.0 576.0 576.0 March 1 ,296.0 1 ,296.0 324.0 648.0 April ] ,200.0 1 ,200.0 300.0 6 00.0 Hay 1 ,296.0 1,296.0 324,, 0 648.0 June 1 , 248 . 0 1 ,248.,0 312.0 624.0 July 1 ,296.0 1 ,296.0 324.0 645.0 August ! ,200.0 1 ,200.0 300.0 600. 0 September 1 ,200.0 1 ,200.0 300.0 600.0 October 1 ,296.0 ! ,296.0 324.0 648.0 November 1 ,200.0 1 ,200.0 600.0 600. C Dec''-n:ber 950.0 960,0 480.0 480.0 F i xe ci c X pe n J i t ij n^ '.s 107.3 124.8 60.0 23. S Co Free land maximum 10.0 3.7 3.0 1.0 Coffee 1 and mi ni mura 10,,0 3.7 ^.0 1.0 Existing coffee 10.0 3.7 3.0 1.0 r.jmi 1 y men 2.0 0 G I.O I'sen employed 2,0 4.0 1.0 1.0 Al lotm-nt of quota 142.5 53.4 42.7 1 ; .2 71 < C7. '■n c u c c CJ o o u o en ao| v£ ^ !| r^ O I (X) LT, LA ! o LA LA CTv LA I vO CO i o ■-l-\ o o o o OOOOOu-\laOO — oo CM J- J- o o o o o o — — " — — -:r -4* I o o o o o o o o o o o OOOOlalAlaOOOO MD vD r-^ 1^ r>'i LA LA r^ O ' — — o o o o o o o — G-A CTi o o o o o o O LA o o oocovDooJ-J-j-ocoo— oo — J- j-cslvOO J" I — CM o o o o o o — — — — lA LA o o o o o o o O LA o o r-. Oa-iOOODOOOOJ-^DO — OJO CM CA CA 00 PO ■ — ' — ^ LA I .- o o o o O O LA o o o o o o o o o o o o o o O O O O CM \,0 CO o o o o — r-^ o CM rA — CA — CM LA o o o o o o o o O O LA o o o o o o o o O CM O OD r- (Tv LA lA (TV O 00 J- — -d- -j -o no , o ■ oo CO C-J CM ■4- o o o o o o oooor--d-cri-^ooo VO L.A O'A O CA O O LA CX) o o — cr\ CM — — CA ■ — UA — oooooooo O O 1^ J- o o CO CO — VD — O ^^ -J- O O — — UA CA • J .;r CM CS, LA CA r- — C^i ■ — o o o o O O O o o o:; 00 o o O O O vO O xO vC ^' -^ CO O — --t ^ o, .-si — OA CTi CTv i>J vO J" — ~ c:> o o o o o — ■ lA LTv CM CM O O O O O O .— lA LA CM fNI O O O o o o — — -- L,'> '-A C^4 CM --. < c to !_ V- .— (r .— . cu :> •a '-\ - tr •_ ^■> i3 ( _ 0) u ?) ;>. G !_ ;^ ^.'^ "i" L, •iJ 10 11 iT' >- '^ X.' i_ OJ —J :^ L- :j .— Cj *c.' c u. o .•_j (_ 1) .n . — CT; L- lU o; • • o -C (j I. a n _J ',_ J) o -O — C C3 r — — c T; 'J-; 1- ■r-' — ■ jr -J I- o .— CJ >- 3 ,J o (U MJ •— £ o ft) c _3 ^0 u J_i - ■ ;Z. .o 1- S_ > c — en cl J-' > 4--' -:-' a; CU ..— u ^ U CI i^ , — i_ fO ■^ Q Cj. ro ■ n 3 (U o Q: " ■1 ^n C) CD -:-' ^> rj _j ■^■- '-(- Tj o-> M i_; f- '-1— ' — O J"^ „~ ■1"* > v_ *- - -.-' '.— CJ iO Co .'.— n v^- o Q o ,— Ci- — ! — : o — O <.J r;^ i_> >- I =; 0) 0) -o E X) 0) u S o-i E u. O 1/1 OJ o e c ~- o 1/-, C?\ 01 ■5 0 1- u fU in c 0} 1_ •^ • a) CM cu **" LU -n 0 C u 0) (U , — -c: l-~ 3 O c .« I/) E >- I- ,—• lO -^ 1 • u a) 1- i- 0 ..— '-f— ■0 -a >-j 0 0) !_ LJ 1) X ■D Q. U1 C 0) 0 1- u fl> 2 1> ^ o d' .— £ -0 > Ql -J %.-m. -C ■^ r Ui xw i-J lo «-/ X — -■ fD -c ') c CJ 'J O": s. C^ c C 0 i_ -iJ .— 1 — aj ■r -a . — -^ i __ 0 > Z} /I c . — 'rt dj >- 1) .~< u c ■-J <~ ir •T ■-.) -C 0 .„ •J 0 ,.- 'l— s_ -;_* 'j"; 0 "O '— ^— to CD i- 172 Coefficients for citrus, stravvberry and pineapple producing activities, Alaj uela Acti vi ty I tern Profit Labor: January February March Apri 1 May June July August Septerriber October November December Land t All year June-August September-May 1 nves tment Ops rati ng capi tal Lii'e transfer Orange transfer Sti'evjberry transfer pi niajipi e tran^.fer Rotation , Rorat ion St rav'ber beans I es Potation, cucurbits Rotation, tomatoes Special credit Limes Granges Straw- ber ri es Pine- apples ■1,767.6 -2,013.6 -12,817.2 -5,853.0 55.0 54.0 450.0 90.0 10.0 54.0 450.0 90.0 10.0 14.0 450.0 450.0 10.0 14.0 450.0 384.0 55.0 54,0 195.0 439 . 0 55.0 54.0 195.0 234.0 71.0 62.0 195.0 372.0 71.0 54.0 225.0 324.0 58.0 54.0 425.0 2.58.0 10.0 !4.0 395.0 22s. 0 10.0 14.0 . 500.0 0 10.0 14.0 401.0 0 1.0 1.0 0 4.0 0 0 1.0 0 0 0 2.0 0 150.0 162.0 0 0 '60.0 249.0 6,090.0 4,462.5 400.0 0 0 0 0 1 ,020.0 0 0 0 0 - 250.0 Q 0 0 0 - 73.0 1.0 1.0 10.0 0 1.0 i.O 0 0 1.0 l.G 0 0 1.0 1.0 c 0 450.0 ~ 249 . 0 -5,090.0 -4,^^2.5 Coefficients for corn producing activities, Alajuela 173 Ac t i vi ty I tern Prof] t Labor: January February March Apri 1 May June July August September October No/eiTiber December Land: Apri 1-October Al 1 year Operati ng capi tal Corn transfer Special cred i t Yield increase -4^9.5 ■715.0 -25K9 0 0 7i^.O 0 0 2^4.0 0 0 36.0 272.0 k.O 0 90.0 90.0 ifl.O ?3.0 98.0 ifl.O 18,0 18.0 58.0 18.0 18.0 72.0 0 0 0 90.0 90.0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1.0 1.0 0 0 0 KO 351. if 551. if ^itq.9 80.0 - 90.0 - 60.0 351. if -551. if •-li+9.9 1.0 - 1.0 0 Coefficients for bean producing activities, Alajuela Vk Acti vi ty I tern Profit Labor: January Apr! 1 May June July August September October December Land: Apr) 1 -September September- December Operating capital Rotation, beans B3an transfer Special credi t -521.0 0 2.0 ■60.8 92. 51. 65. 51. 0 0 1.0 0 ^55.2 1.0 ■ 20.0 •^55.2 28. ,0 0 0 0 0 0 22. 0 0 60. 0 0 1. 0 51. 7 i. 0 5. 0 51. -7 ■139.1 i+8.0 0 0 0 0 0 72.0 0 72.0 0 1.0 122.0 1.0 10.0 122,0 175 Coefficients for corn and bean, and peanut producing activities, Aiaj uela I tem Corn-bean Peanut Profit Labor: March Apri 1 May June July August September Oc cober November December Land: March- December March-October Augus t- November Opera ti ng cspi tal Corn trans Fer Bean transfer Peanut transfer ,0^.\ k.O 28.0 65.0 29,0 48.0 0 9^.0 hS.O 55.0 51.0 1.0 0 0 8/7.0 kS.O 18.0 0 ■78.0 72.0 0 2.0 60.0 51.0 40.0 34.0 44.0 0 0 0 42. •20, ■ 4. 0 -362.0 0 0 c 0 0 i^42.0 48.0 12.0 72.0 0 0 0 1.0 3^2.0 0 0 • 20.0 76 > > < I o o I LA I O o o I o o o o o o o c OJ'-J-O^C^CNIOOOOOO ro rv^ fy^. f»-( — — o o o o f^ o o -d" o 0^ o — CM — o o o o o o o o o o -zf'^MricNicsiocoocoo-J- r^ r»-> ra — • — cr\ ro O J" O O 1^ O — CM -a fD o o o o o o o o cNi o • ■ * • • • • • • CX) OOCNICMJ-OOOO-CTO CO — O O O \^ O \/ vO — — J- O T. O 1_ J- — CM CM ro o •» .. «. * 2 1 CM 1 0) o o o o cMCNjj-ooooo-croo ^ ^ — o . CM o o o o o o o o OMCslOvJDOCMcMOOCsJOOO ltn ltn o ct, la LTi -:.t tr\ -d" rA OO rA CM CM CM CA O O CM o CA O O O — v^ O CT. O CM PA o o o J- O O O O O O LT-. ' — c 9} 0) > o 0) 0) (3 O •i-J IT) v-> CD CD T3 cu f5 '/I (!) .C I C' o o o o o o o cnI cm o 'A O CM OT vD --T O r> LA LA O O^. Li", -J- — cX! O .-A tv-\ (A CM CN — CM J- o o o -r o o o o o o c^ CO LTi ~ 1> > U u 'I- o Oi O -J ,.Q L. ' 1. ft) Ct I .V, J -5 ' T a a-. m a -J -; i'j ',' "^ ij .c -' --- ai — u 1. ;a L>- , _ J_ ^ — 1 ■J^ i_ ■'I; (IJ ._ ^ A. ;£; u. D. 10 •-i « >• 1 tC L. 1 >- 42 1.. I. 4-i >^ u 0 s_ .0 I -O ai 1; Iv D -~- ;- c c Z'j '.. .... i} .— ■TJ c: -O !_ ^ ;-t U 03 e Cl 6 Q L. IL. < :^ (U 0 10 L ' ■J-. 4-< .T fj -n '; 0 ;_ i_ 0 !i) a ■n 1- C.1 — t I 'H 177 Coefficients for sweetpotato and cassava producing activities, Alajuela Swsetpo tato Cassava 1 tem 1 2 1 1 2 3 Profit -l,262.'!+5 -3^.25 -669.80 -1,277.75 ■ -1 ,029.00 Labor: February 0 33^+. 00 0 0 0 Apri 1 192.00 0 120.00 0 0 May 116.00 0 0 80.00 80.00 June 10^.00 0 0 0 198.00 , July 28.00 0 102.00 0 0 August i:38.00 0 0 180.00 56.00 September 0 0 128.00 60.00 0 October 0 384.00 0 0 80.00 November 0 96,00 85.00 85.00 0 December 0 24.00 0 0 0 Land: All year 0 0 1.00 2.00 2.00 Apr! i -August 1.00 0 0 0 0 October- February 0 1.00 0 0 0 Augijs t-Apri 1 0 0 1.00 0 0 May- June 0 0 0 0 1.00 Operati ng cap; tal 831.15 228.00 200. CO 1,772.00 1 ,300.00 Cassava transfer 0 0 -150.00 - 200.00 ■ - 275.00 Sweetpotato transfer - 300.00 • -100.00 0 0 0 Special credi t - 891.15 ■ -228.00 -200.00 -1,772.00 ■ -1 ,300.00 178 Coefficients for buckv.heat and chickpea producing activities, Alajuela I tem Buckv-^heat Chi ckpea Profit Labor: January February March October Land: January-March October- February Operati ng capi tal Buckvvheat transfer Chickpea transfer Spec i a 1 cred i t -56.7 12,0 0 120.0 0 1.0 0 ko.k - 8.0 0 -ko.k ■82.0 66. ,0 20. ,0 0 22. ,0 0 1. ,0 77. .2 0 5. .0 77. ,2 79 Ccef f icltrits for cucumber ard tomato prodijcing activities, Aiajueia Cucumber Toiiia to ! tem Frori t -] ,601.2 -1 ,602.0 -2,5^^5.0 -2,^6^.0 Labor: January 0 350.0 592,0 0 Februat y 0 157.0 592.0 0 March 325.0 825.0 0 0 Apri 1 157.0 0 o-' 0 May 825.0 0 0/ 102.0 June 0 0 0 522.0 July 0 0 0 2SS.0 August 0 0 0 279.0 September 0 0 168.0 138.0 October 0 0 208.0 , 378.0 N'oveinLer 0 0 390,0 120,0 December 0 0 37^.0 J 0 Land: March" May 1.0 0 c 0 January-Mar ch 0 1.0 0 0 May-October 0 0 0 1.0 Septembcr-Fi ehruary 0 0 <-0 0 Operating capi tal 1,^99.2 1,^99.2 1,7VlC 1,655.0 Rotation, toma tees 0 0 2.0 2.0 Rotation, cucu rbi C5 if.O ^^.0 0 0 Cucumber trans rer 140,0 ]kO.Q 0 0 Toriiato transfe r 0 0 - 27.7 (1 ,2 Special credit -l,i<99.2 -1 ,ifS9.2 -1 ,7^^.0 -1 ,655.C Coefficients for sv.eet pepper, dairy, and pigeon pea producing activities, AlajuC. la 180 Pi geon Feppet Dai ry _pea ! tem 1 2 Profits -1,937.8 -1,243.0 - k67.2 -303.9 Labor: January 189.0 196,0 10,0 6.0 February 189, 0 156.0 10.0 6.0 March 159.0 156.0 10.0 160.0 April 189.0 156.0 10.0 2'f0,0 May 0 0 10.0 170,0 June 0 0 17.0 i^0,0 July 0 102.0 10.0 0 August 150,0 60.0 li+.O 6,0 September 17^.0 60.0 10.0 6.0 October 168.0 0 10. 0 2if0,0 November 168,0 100.0 !0.0 0 December 92,0 70.0 10,0 0 Land : All year 0 0 1,0 1.0 July-Apri 1 0 1.0 0 0 August- Apr! ! ].0 0 0 0 1 nves In-.ent 0 0 9.0 0 Ope rati ng capi tal 1,298.0 920.0 1,277,2 272,0 Ro ta t i on , s t r a wbe r r i e s 0 0 1,0 0 Rotatior!, beans 0 0 1.0 1.0 Rotation, cucurbits 0 0 1,0 0 Rotation, tomatoes 2.0 2,0 1,0 0 Pepper transfer 9.0 7.5 0 0 fli !k transfer 0 0 20,0 1-1 Calf tr'ons for 0 0 0.9 0 Pigeon pa 3 t r a n s f e r 0 0 0 - 20.0 Special credl £ -1 ,293.0 - 920,0 -1 ,2/7.2 •-272. 0 181 ■r, CD c 1_ to c a? <+- o o o U> c o o 1/1 1) O > ■ . — o IT o (.J CM I U 0) fO c 3 (J to — a> c O (t) _v; to u (I> 3 .C CQ 5 I/-, c 'T: e CQ o csi! 1 "1 ooooooooooo o o — oooooooooooo — o ooooooooooo — oo o o o en OOOOOOO" ooo OOOOOOOOO — OOOO O I o vO o . o o • • • ij-vooooooo — ooooo un I o o OOOOOOO'-OOOOOO o CM o o o oo — ooooooo CM o • • O 1 o o cnooooooooc o !V~1 O O O ! — . — ■- o O O O O O O O C5 o l\ O O O 1^ * Q » » * ^,-; — — — v") o o o o c. o o o o o 1,0 ■j) a) '1- oT y C to iO (■3 1 - r: CL O i- L- o 1/1 a. i-> o '■•'- ■?■ , — c _s: o D C C: 1_ I. O (15 fi. (-■- < «.■> to '-> :- )82 0/ < D". 0) -O en <4.- C o I O !U .'3 5 O ! o o r^ O cr o o o LA o o o o o o o o o o o o o o — J1 l_ O 0) • a O o o o o Q o (U r^ Q. in o 1 c 1. C>_ 1- u 1- c U O ■T 1) l- 1. 'U_ 0 0 0 1 U u u) in • -. .^ U u OJ Q) 'SI M- i_ .^1 L_ c V M- L. V. v_ iTJ .— ■■l- 14- C ._] n -.— 1) >^ >. o >- a n '■3 1: IJ 1- (TJ OJ '_; o o l_ '._ Ui l- l.'t \_ 1. I-) '_ iT c OJ l.'l V. v_ n ,-) C > .■a ._ .1- o. '\J a. i'v U i_ ro 1_ iO ro ,_) -~' '_ ■i-j 0 i_ '_, *_ (J 0) lU "J O il< UJ Q. o_ QJ 0 0 T L- J J .'_) D. CI. (I) a) \_ 0) ^_ .,:3 -O I. Ji (_ C. a. s.. i_ 0 .a ^ ^' ^ >- 0 0-! _ CO O'' o Dl o 5 ^ u ^ >-.' I'O m I) U -w £ -(-; ;.- ro • ^ ..- Ci. c^ J- ,\> 0> *''. c ."^ L_ C lU ."j '0 ;' rJ I'.' 01 CJ "^ c. re 3 0 0) LI 0 r: >/ r— o ij^ .,-; E 10 rj .— "} "D V— 1- ... I.. ■(■I c c >~. or E n ■D ^.1— i.n 0 0 OJ .0 '— ■ — o - . -. 1_ ^ . L. 4W IJ '.~t .— q; 0 3 5 0 u JI .. J -J I o '"^^ o CT /•■ v': ■i. 'U n.. w V) 0 1'"" (-J Coffee harvesting activities, Alajuela 183 I ten-i Fami 1 y Hired Profit Labor: January February November December Harvest labor: January February November Decen.ber Coffee harvest -ifO.O 5.0 k.O h.Q 5.0 5.0 k.O k.O 5.0 0. 0, 0. 0, 0 0 0 0 Coefficients of right hand side constraints for Alajuela farms 18^ Fa rns ! tem 9 10 11 12 Labor: January 2j8'+.0 1 ,248.0 936.0 1,716.0 February 2,016.0 1,152.0 834.0 1,584.0 March 2,025.0 1,174.0 436.0 1,296.0 Apri I 1,875.0 1,131.0 450.0 1 ,200.0 May 2,025.0 1,174.0 486.0 1,296.0 June 1,950.0 1,131.0 463.0 1,248.0 July 2.025.0 1,174.0 i^86.0 1 ,296.0 August 1,875.0 1,087.0 450.0 1 ,200.0 S'dotCfT.ber 1,375.0 1,087-0 450.0 1 ,2C0.0 October 2,025.0 1,174.0 486.0 1,296.0 November 1 ,950.0 1,125.0 750.0 1,650.0 Decemb3r 1 ,680.0 960.0 720„0 1,320.0 Land hO.O 15.0 iO.5 5.5 Operating capital 22.200.0 15,750.0 8,850.0 1,115.0 Harvest labor, fan^:ily: January 62'4,0 468.0 780.0 1 ,404.0 February 576.0 432.0 720.0 1,296.0 liovetr.ber 430.0 375.0 600,0 1,350.0 B;cenber 480.0 360.0 6C0.0 1,080.0 Supervision of labor: 'nrruiiy 3,744.0 2,18^,0 . ' 9 ; n 1,560.0 Fetjr.tery 3.456.0 2,016.0 5 76.0 i,4ua.o March 3,888.0 2,268.0 648.0 i ,620.0 Apri i 3,600.0 2 J 00.0 600.0 1 ,500.0 May 3,888.0 2,268.0 648.0 1 ,620.0 June 3,744.0 2,184.0 624.0 1 ,560.0 July 3,828.0 2 . 263 , 0 648.0 1 ,620.0 August 3,600.0 2,100.0 600. 0 1 ,500,0 Sep'e.iiiber 3,600.0 2,100.0 600.0 1 .500.0 October 3,388.0 2,268.0 648.0 1 ,620. C Ncv?.nber •3,600.0 2.. iCO.O 600.0 1,500.0 Oeceniber 2,880,0 1 .680.0 'iBO.O 1 ,200.0 R o 1 0 1 i 'J .-! , s t r 3 v\' b e i r i o s 40,0 13.0 !0.5 3.5 Rotation, bear.s 40,0 !5.0 10.5 5.5 Rotation. cL'C'jr bi ts 40,0 ! - . 0 10.5 5-5 P.o t3 1 ! on , toiia tee s iiO.O 15.0 10.5 Fix's J expenditures 485.7 56.7 79. 0 Co i' f i" e ( a nd max 1 mum 40.0 ■I5..O 5.0 2.5 Coffee land -.•linlmum ^0.0 1:^,0 5-0 E.c'stin^ coffee 4 0.0 :5.0 r- /*, 2.5 !-3n":i ly riion :'.,o 2.0 1.0 3.0 Man £-.(;iployed 10.0 5.0 1,0 2 . 0 Al Ic-tiTi'int 750.0 225,0 /5.0 18.7 185 Coefficients of coffee producing activities 1 through '+, Acosta Act • • 4. a 1 VI ty 1 tem 1 2 3 4 Profit -677.00 -676.35 -490.00 -489.40 Labor: January 16,00 3K00 40,00 40.00 February 15.00 68.00 10,00 10.00 March 68.00 71.00 32.00 32.00 April 51.00 18.00 23.00 13. OG Hay 38.00 18.00 21.00 31.00 June 18.00 18.00 14.00 14.00 July 56.00 73.00 57.00 114.00 A jgust 47. OC 30.00 72.00 72.00 September 32.00 16.00 57.00 0 October 0 16.00 40.00 40.00 i n vestment 12.80 12.80 0 0 Operat: ng ca pi tal 5^7.75 5^7. '75 315.20 315.20 Land, all ye ;ar 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 Coffee land maximum l.OC 1.00 1.00 1.00 Coffee land mini mum 1,00 1.00 1.00 1.00 Coffee trans fer 0 0 - 10.00 - 10,00 Yield potential - l''+.00 - 14.00 0 0 Yield change 0 0 10.00 10.00 '^Two activities viere derived from each budget to allov; flexibility in vo rk scheduling. 186 Coefficients for coffee producing activities 5 through 7, Acosta Acti vi ty I ten Profit L'^bor : March Apri 1 May July August September October Opera t i ng cipi tal Land: Al I year Coffee land maxi rtium Coffee land mini mum Coffee transfer Yield change ■155.3 ■156,0 ■15.0 ifO.O 40. C 0 60,0 80.0 0 6'4.C kk.O 0 50.0 120.0 0 70.0 0 0 0 0 80.0 100.0 100.0 0 116.0 116.0 0 1.0 1.0 1.0 1.0 1,0 1.0 1,0 1,0 1.0 6.0 - 6,0 - 2,0 6.0 6,0 2.0 187 Coefficients for coffee-fruit producing activities, Acosta tern Cof fee-orange- banana Acti vi ty Coffee-orange Prof i t Labor: January February March Apri I May June July August October December Land Coffee land maximum Coffee land rpinimum Coffee transfer Orange traiisfer Banana transfer Yield change (coffee) •^59.2 90.0 90.0 90.0 70.0 40.0 10,0 60.0 0 15 120 1 1 0 0 0 0 1.0 5.0 10.0 1.0 5.0 ,0 0 •300.0 30.0 30.0 40.0 20. 112. 0 0 120.0 100.0 20.0 1.0 1.0 1.0 • 6.0 ■ 30.0 • 0.5 6.0 Coefficients for fruit producing activities, Accsta 188 Act i vi ty — =z B' lack- I tem Orange 1 Orange 2 L i me s berries Profit -2,019.6 -1,^32.1 -1,767.6 -8 ,578,7 Labor: January 5^.0 36.0 55.0 3^0.0 February 5^.0 36.0 55.0 28c. 0 March I'+.O 0 10.0 280.0 Apr i 1 ]k.O 0 10.0 180.0 May s'+.o 36.0 55.0 lUQ.O June 5^.0 36.0 55.0 180.0 July 62.0 32.0 71.0 180.0 August s'+.o 32.0 71.0 l^lO.O September 5^.0 32.0 58.0 80.0 October 1^.0 0 10.0 30.0 Noveir.ber M+.o 0 iO.O i'+0,0 December 14.0 0 10,0 80.0 I nvestrront 162.5 53.2 150.0 0 Ope rati ng capi tal 2^^9 . 0 155.0 ^50.0 3 ,68'f.O Land 1.0 KO 1.0 1.0 Orange transfer -1 ,020.0 - 533.3 0 0 Lime transfer 0 0 - 'iGO.O 0 Blackberry transfer 0 0 0 - i-so.o Special credit - 249 . 0 - 155.0 - 450,0 -3 ,6G^.O CoefficienLs for corn-bean producing activities, Acosta 189 Act i vi ty 1 tern Profit Labor: April May June August September October December Land Operati ng capi tal Corn transfer Bean transfer Scecial credi t -^38.4 ■117.7 185.5 12,0 20.0 10.0 36.0 2'+.0 50.0 2i+.0 20.0 0 0 ^0.0 0 5^.0 48.0 60,0 21.0 0 0 0 160.0 7^.0 KO 1.0 1,0 318.0 86.0 135.0 29.0 - GA - 16.0 11,0 - 9.6 - 6.6 313.0 - 86.0 -135.0 Coefficients for dairy producing activities, Acosta 190 Acti vi ty 1 teiTi 1 2 3 k 5 Prof i t -it76.9 - 68.7 - 63.0 -467.2 -188.2 Lsbor: January 20,0 15.0 15.0 10.0 10.0 February 20.0 15.0 15.0 10.0 10.0 March 20.0 15.0 15.0 10.0 10.0 Apri 1 20.0 15.0 15.0 10.0 10.0 Hay 20.0 15.0 15.0 10.0 10.0 June 27.0 15.0 15.0 17.0 17.0 July 24.0 29.0 35.0 10.0 10.0 August 2i+.0 29.0 35.0 1 4. 0 14.0 September 24.0 15.0 35.0 10.0 10.0 October 2'4. 0 15.0 15.0 10.0 10.0 Novenber 20.0 15.0 15.0 10.0 10.0 December 20.0 15.0 15.0 10.0 10.0 Land 2.5 2.5 5.C 1.0 1.0 Opcrati ng cap! tai 2,289.9 608.7 603.0 1,277.2 977.2 i nvest.'ienl 19.0 6.0 6.0 9.0 9.0 I'',' 1 k transfer - 30.0 - IQ.O - 10.0 - 20.0 - 10.0 Caif transf.-jr 0 0.9 C,8 0.9 - 80.0 Special credit -2,259.9 -608.7 ■■603.0 1 ,2:'7.2 -977.2 Coefficients for beef producing activities, Acosta 191 Acti vi ty I tern Profit Labor: January February March April May June Jul y August September October November December Land ! nvestment Operati ng capi tal Calf transfer Speci al credi t -li+2.0 5.0 5.0 5.0 5.0 5.0 13.0 13.0 13.0 5.0 5.0 6.0 5.0 1.5 8.0 862.0 ■ 0.7 -862.0 - 63.0 1.0 1.0 1.0 1.0 1.0 1.0 3'^.0 3^.0 1.0 1.0 1.0 1.0 5.0 6.0 603.0 - 0.5 -603.0 0) 1) .13 192 ooooooooo c o o o o o o o — o ■SI c re ll) cc ooooooo — oo o o c c^ c o o o o Csl o o o < c o o u o o — , — — O rv~v o I o o o o c 0) (J o u .•^ o o o r-j ,_ ,- o O — O O O O c to 5.1 C o u (1) OJ rj) a' X ol CM O O Csl O u,"v . — . — O u\ — o o o o (NJ I Hi o 'J c CD o (U a <•(- '■■t- o o u ,'j ly •V 01 M- a) I- 1- 1, 5.. O l/l c ■i) ■9 (J a > C «~ V*-. t.;_ '1- '^ T3 t/) , — 10 1/1 l/l ■j) (0 V^ 4-J 03 i.j -.'J c c I" -C +-' r^ u a; ••5 o in Q V •o i . u 1— 1. -r-j 1) 0) rE i_ ) -■ -;-' 4-' -!-- *-.. (U OJ M o. \_ o c ..- t"u Ti- CJ (.J i^i" I— Q. (.-■> ,T1 i- CJ 193 I/) o 0) C 3 o C O o > > -t-j u < 1/1 c 1_ o 0) 1/) Q CI m ca o o o o o o o o Lr\ o o o o • m • o o o — — — o o o o o o <^-J"000 O-— ' — — oooo o o o o o • • • • • o>,o^o — — — coo I o o o O O O o OO-J-OOOOOOOOO — O o in "J CU 'J '"- ri. 1/1 1/1 D 1- 1- '^ •- _c :5 ■I-' c o e a; ■- o — -C X) c cn o c .— — Ul Q. r— o o 1/1 l/l o c S- UJ s: +-I -t-i 1/1 0) * > Ul 1- 0) Q u -C 1- « Q. (U Xi J-J ID .— -C 3 1/1 y-- I- o 3 M- O ■ — c 5 Ji o \_ l_ — CD LO J -^ Xi .— o; u > lO p: o .JI ■■A u Q. tJ l/l O U 1. .— ii» ^■_ ■> -^ ai 1/1 v_ 13 Cj CI 2 lO c . •xi 17. >- c ja -^ O ... i — m > -£3 u •- O c +-> V. .- 0.0 May 2,835.0 486.0 405.0 486.0 June 2,730.0 468.0 385.0 468.0 July 2,835.0 486.0 405.0 486.0 August 2,625.0 450.0 375.0 450.0 September 2,625.0 450.0 375.0 450.0 October 2,916.0 486.0 6'i8.0 648.0 November 2,700.0 450.0 600.0 600.0 December 2,100.0 360.0 480.0 480,0 Operating capital 51,^22.7 5,9^5.0 825.0 675.0 Land 101.5 16.0 2.0 6.5 Harvest labor, family: January 62t|.0 4^8.0 624.0 312.0 February 576.0 437.0 576.0 288.0 October 6^+8.0 486.0 648.0 324.0 November 600.0 450,0 600. 0 300.0 December '+80. 0 360.0 480.0 240.0 Supervision of labor: .'anuary 5..30''4.0 936.0 312.0 £24.0 February ^,856.0 864.0 288.0 5 '6.0 Morch 5,508.0 472.0 324.0 648,0 April 5,100.0 900.0 300.0 600,0 May 3,508.0 972.0 324.0 648. 0 .June 5,30'+.0 936.0 312.0 624,0 July 5,508.0 972,0 324.0 648.0 August 5,100=0 900„0 300.0 600.0 5epten:ber 5,100.0 900,0 300.0 600.0 October 5,508.0 97i.O 324.0 643. 0 . November 5,100.0 900.0 300.0 600,0 December '^oso.o 720.0 240.0 (• i xe d e X pt; nd I L u >" e s '475 . 0 n ,5 4.2 29.9 Fa mi ly men 4.0 i.O i.O Hen employed 9.0 0.0 0.0 1.0 Coffee land maximum 90,0 7.0 2.0 1.5 Coffee lorid miriimum SCO 7.0 2.0 US uxi 5t i nu coffee 90.0 7 . 0 2,0 1.5 Al lotment 675.0 52.5 7.5 5.6 LITERATURE CITED 1. Abercrcnibie , K, C, "Population Grov:o Muni ci pal . A pi-oi(;ct report prepared For the Co:Tii te d'e Di vers i f i c-?.cicn. Tui'rialba, Costa Rica: I968. '0, Bc", avi'jes Ro^'les, Oscar, "'"he Anrj culture of ths^ Rio Grande Riy>-r 'iilli!?^^ 9.\,. the Centra_1_ PI ■^teau_j__Cos_ta _RJ c^ w_[ liL^Slii^^iJ'i.-^rfiiiaP.ii on Cof f':c_ r-ar^FS, Thesis. Ithaca. tJew York: Cornel i University, '19 5 7.""" !1. Bieb'^i", Jolm '.. An Econ'Jini c /■uoiysisof 01 "S rs 1 f i c'i t ;_on of Coffee J!i'.?ilil?J,,n.9.-,AL^:^J5j. .Qpj;JL^„lli.?.?.- •^' '-'nivcrsity of Florida report ^>rGp^r'-^d roi- the '}. G. AiO f'lission ' r: Costa Rica. San Jose, Costa Rica: :96B. luC-, 197 12. Brooke, D. L. and P.. L. Quails, Prcduct.iori sncJ Ha'-kating of F 1 o :• i eg St rs;\'be r r i es . Agricultural Economics '-iirr.eo Report EC 67-3. 'October, I966,' 13. Brovjn, Lester P, "The V/orld Food cind Popui r,t ion Problerp." Foreign Agriculture, 5 (5): 3-4. January 30, 1967. ]k, Caro Costas, Ruben, Jose Vincente Chandler, and Jecinto Figarella, "Productivity of Intensively Managed Pastures cf Five Grasses on Steep Slopes of Hu.r.id Mountains of Puerto Rico." Journal of Agriculture of the ijnjversity of Puerto Rico, kO ( 1 ) : 99-111. 15- Carvajal, Manuel J, and James E. Ross. Fact Sheets on Costa Ri can Agr i cul ture. A University of Florida report prepared In cooperation with the U. S. AID liission i i' Costa Rics. San Jose'^ Costr Rica: I968, IS. Castillo, Carlos M. Growth and integral: ion in Centra 1^ Aiherica. New Yori<: Frederick A, Praag-r, Publishers, I966. Castro, Juan J, and Jc-es E. Ross. Factors A f fee t ! r, g A ;t r i h u s i ne; s J n ye St inert i n Cost_a R i ca, A University of Florida report pre- pared in cooperation with the U. S. AID Mission in Costa Rica. y^ San Jose, Costa Rica: !369. 8. Collaco, Oscar. "Ccsto Proj.edio do Produccion por i'lanzana ce Cultivo." Work Sheets of Scrcion de Juntas Ruraie? de Credito Agricola, Oapartmento de Credito Rural, Banco fiaclcnal de Cosra Rica, 1967. 19. Consejo Superior Unlversario. ''-'X'"^i:l'._"i ^I-r'^"!'-^^- li? ''■S-'^J-'CIPJ. Humanos_ en Centroamer i ca. Estudic d^s Recursos Huranos en Centroamar ica No. 6, Ciudad Un; versi tarM a , Costa Rica; 1366. 20. C u 1 1 j , T h o n 3 s V , C a 5 t orb e a r P rod 1 1 c_t i o n i ri_J;_h e__Mj sjj ?_?_! p P i _ f^e 1 1 3 , Mississippi AgricL'l tural Zxpar i n-ent Station Bulletin 677&. '563. 21 ;•',! ss- issippi Agricultural F.xpe rjf.-ient Siiation Bulletin &7^. 1963- Dalry-plc, Orria G. The p i ye r 5 i f i ca t j on_ oj^ Ah.LU.'^I A'-'f 'JlL J^"^g'-:;Xl'^ in i,P.ss Devalopfcci C^iiintries. A report of the ! ntemarioi-id!] Agr i oul ti^ra 1 DeveloD^pent Service. U, S. Di;c.5ri;nar!t of Ai^r ' c:u' tur; 1368. Diieccic'r. Genera! de Estadiitica y Cei^.-^o. ^363, Sap .lose. Costa Rica. Censo Aqropeci-iar io 2k. Comerelo Exterio/ da Costa Rica ig68, San '■''-■'^ /■ Costa Rica, ^ , iJopubUsh'^d co.npuver output suirnsar i z' ng the 1963 agr i '.-ul ti.i ra 1 census by district for major crops. San Jt:se', Cosia Rica. 198 ?.c. Facuitad dr- Agronomia. I nforme de Trobajo Anexo de I'crti cul turj. E~t3cion Exp-'^riruontal Aon cola "Ffibio BaudrMt- Moreno.' ' A report of the Universidad de Costa Rica. 1953. 27. Ferna'-idcz, Cailos Enrique. 'Adaptfcicn de la Produccion Latin- arnerlcana de Cafe a la Demanda Hundal." Revista Cafe tal era. OctLibre de 1967, 29-31. 28. Fior'ida Depnrrnent of Agriculture. Citrus Siinrr.ary. F'orida Aqri- cuUu rai Statistics. I966. 29. Food and Aariculture Organization. "Coffee Production." Monthly Bulletin of Agriculture and Stat .sties, 1 7 (11): 21. 'Jovembe r , T968. 30. Gilbert, Alvin E. "Coffee in Latin America: A Bless i no and a Buraen." Fo re i g n A q r i c u It u re , 5 (I5): 10. April 10, I9S7. 31. Gooding, H, .]. "The Agronomic Aspects of Pigeon Peas." Field CLoplAk st_r;a^cj:j_ , 15 ( 1 C ) : 1 - 5 . 1 9 'S 2 . 32. Haarer. A. E, Modern Coffee Production. London: Leonard Hill Limited, I962. 33. Meady, Earl 0. and Wilfred Candler. Li near rroqramrii_ng_ Methods. Ames J > o'a'B : The Iowa State University Press, 1958. 2,k. _! ate rna t i cna 1 _ Coffee f-.^qreeraent, 1 968. V,'orld Coffee information Center. Washington, "Diversification Fund" Cliaoter XVI, Ar t i ci e 5''-+. 35. "israe! Expands StraK'berry Market." foroi qn Agr i ctjl ture , 7 (33): 16, Seple>nber 2?., I969. 36. Junta 03 Defensa del Tabaco, Invest! g a c i o n .Sob re i*" r o d 1 1 c c ; o n e ingresos del Tahaco. San Jose', Costa Ric.i; lye'/. 37. llenoen, Peter B. In c,e-na t : onal ;.coj_cjt.J_j Ke.-j Jersey: Prentice Hail, Inc., 196' E!ig1ev-;ooa C ! f fs. ?9 Kinrnan, Murray. "Sesame as ? Don^.estic ! n:'i.!.' tr i al Oilseed Crop.'' Chsjnu r q i_c J,}\ •'[GSi , 13: 6- 3 . Fe b r ua ry , 19^''-. 39. A Year of Froaress in Sesame." Chiemuroic Dicest, 17: 'y. Apri 1 , 1958. ^;n. K.'auss, F, G. '■''''i._^i_3.1'<-- "]„.•?■- 'I CCaJenus indicu^) LiLL.Jiil£Ii'.Z?iL^ilt-.« '-J<.Lti' r ''-..?r'.^ . [[■-J.ll.lPi.i^Il- Hr.v.-ai i Agricul tural Experimei-it Sic, t ion Bi,.i!i£''in llo. 6h, Moi-ch, '93?. trir:_ A_tj :Jn t p ff, G Ci r e d ■ i.-. Zone of ^Ccgta '^ i c-o. A Ur "versity of Florida report ■jr t;vj Agency foi' ! nterna c i ona i Oc-velopnient . Gaine;)- vi ! ie , '.'lor; da: !9':'7. 199 kl. Krome, WiJiiuin H. ''Econcmic View of Litne Growing In Florida." Fconon-.ic Botany, 22 (3): 270-272. Jul y -Seplenber , I968. '43, Lnnsen, P-3u], "Plastic Mulching is a Profitable Practice." Ainerican Fruit Grovjer, 87 (3): 30-32. March, 1967. Vf . L« f tv: \cM , P. i c h a r d H . Th e Price System and Resource Allocation. New York: Holt, RInehart and V/inston, I966. M-5. Lockley, Lawrence C, A Guide to Market Data in Central America. Cank for Economic integration, Tegucigalpa, Honduras, 196'+. ij-S , Magleby, R. 5, "Agricultural Geography; Latin America in Trans- ition," Foreign Aori cul ture , 5 (I5): 11. April 10, 1967. k7 . Martin, John H. and V/arren H. Leonard, Principles of Field Cro[> Production. New York: The MoctT.illan Company, !9'+9. kS. nillikan, Max F, and David Hapgood, No Easy Harvest. Boston: Little, Brown and Company, I367. 49. Hinisterio de Agrlcultura de Guatemala. Costos de Es tablecjini en'.o. Mar, ten i mi en to y Cosecha de Jos Cul ti vos de Hu l_e_j__C.j; c ao__,__C/!_t r i c^ts , V-^IH' Ha, Jocote M^ranon, Soya, Pi na ,_^oco_^ Mango, Papaya y j!.L7."L£rJl?. jlSi^X'^ • ^'^ economic report prepared by the "Los Criilantes" Experiment Center. Muiua, Retalhulcu: 1968. 50. Mini^terio de Agricultur-a y Ganaderia. Cu_i_tj_yos_ Aar_^l_col as__d_£ Costa !';ica i'lar.ual de__ Recoriiandacig.'ies^. Boletifi Tecnico Mo. 35. San Jose'j Costa Rica: I965. 51 e . "Produccion de Fr^joles en la Zona de Atenas-~San Josecitc (Alajuela) Costa Rir.c," Proyecto d 3 i nve s t i oac tones .^^^^Q^HLbLli* ^- 36--N0. 3. M::r2C. iS62. 5/. Muri'iio Argueilo, Gilbert, Pueba de Rend jmi erj'o ccj. VBriedades .'i':_J!?:2.Ll!2' BcletT'r Tecnico No. -:■] , ilinisterlo de Agricul tu ra y Ganaderia, San JosCj Costa Rice: 1963. r!:";v;m-3 n , Peter. F.conorr!; c Ar^ alysis of the ..j; rpJ?l'2Jp;_ oj^__Cc f Fee ^i'JlOltlS"!!.' ■"* i'sport from Rocert R, Nathan Associates to the Oficioa de Plcoi f i cacicn, Pies i dene i a de 'ij Republics, Sao Jose^ CosLii R'ca: uuiy, I966. 5'^. OficMTa do] Z:x^'5. A 1 gj^^incs _Co r.s__( drj^ari ones ^!"' ii- ■ -'''^i£I' vi-^'"' '^' i'^^.i.^'''/L'':^i'.i..i'lf^?J®L'iL^!l.„Q9:2_t.^ C.!Ji£' ^'^rs Josc^, tosta Rica: '1967^ " 35- Oficira '■•= ?1 an i f i cac • om. '•C."'ac'-«r i s t J cas y Probl crnat": de la Eccncr.ia Nacional iS^O- :S ■'^■r! •'' -' l^i-'-'-" 'Pil y •^S.^%Pd.'"J. L'-'iiJ i^S -"I '^SS:D^]D.9L.S^llsi: ^ilS:S^j^ i .JLi>iSL'isI'3— ^, .Ei5^cut3r en ...1^8_ j^_s_l;3_ .?±;L^J_..?XxSi:P.lr>2.^1i£'5.« Pre;; i dene i a dc ] .-?, Republica, San Jose/', i;osta R icc!. 200 56. • JLoiI:?iLQ.'^.'_o. jg- >!.f '"^s Bas.cas de Cos td Rj_ca_ IV. Sectq-^ A'jrop&cuaric 1950-1967. Prssidencia de la Republlca. San .^.o'i'^, Costa Rica. 57. Organii:ai!on of American States, Fan American Union. Production and_ Export Capabi i i ties for Certain Agr i cu 1 tural Froduccj_iji Aaj^_£nd_jVo£e s_se d__^ Washington: 1S66. 58. Ospino, V. F. Mapua] de Costos Basicos de Act i yj dad_es_ Ajrop^e- i^iJiTJ.?!' Banco de Credito AgrFcoia de Cartago. San Jose'', Costa Rica: I966. 59. Pan Aire r I can Coffee Bureau. Coffee and the IJ. S. C_o_nj;'.:T]3_r . New York: lyS't. 60. Pitcher, S, "Brazil's Cof^^ee Tree Eradicarion Progi-am as cf Today." Foreign Agriculture, 3 (22): 67. August IS, I965. 61. SchoM , Joiin C. "Mexico's Grain Problem: A Production Bcom That V/on't Turn Off." Foreign Aqricul ture, 5 (27^: 7. July 3, 1967. 62. Schultz, Theodore V/. Econgmi c. Cri si :^ i -1 World Aqr ; cul tuj-e_. Ann Arbor, Michigan: The LIniversity of Michigan Prnss, I965. f'S. , _...,.. XL?JLlL'31^[llij£_Ijl?.d Lt Lona 1 _ A^^^ New 1-laven, Connect'CL'v; The Yale Uni\'erbitv Press, 1964, 6'+. Sei'vicio Mf tec-ologico Nacional. f'Sh2-}:XriJ:}^119^1^9^S::S^^'^_}l;i'o^. 3an Jose, Cc-:; ta P, ica. 65. Snerman, W. B. and P. J, West gate, .BJ.^ckbe_rr^_Producti en in noflda, riorlda Aqr i cul tu ra 1 Extension Service C! rcuf iir'^'^ZS. May, 1968. 60. Toliev. G, S. and G, 0, Gwver. "! nterna ti cna 1 Trade in Agri- cultural Products in Relation to Economic Deve lopmeri t ," pp. 4 0 3 - ': H-7 , Aqri cul tuidl Developinetit and Economi c__G_i-cn-j t h , ads. H. M, Southworth and B. F, Johnson, Ithaca, Nev; York: Corr.v;!) University Press, 1967. 67. Tosi, Joseph A., ::\- . and Robert F. Voertniar. "Sere Env' i ron:r.';:iral Facrot-s in the Fconom'c Dave ] opn-er; ;: of the Tropics," Econcr^i c i?"i^Mj:;iL'^Llv, '^0: ic9-?05. July, !:.6'!-, t'-i. Iropica! /-vyr i r.u 1 t ura i Mun"geir.e-, t Co., inc. A_ Proj^osai fpr_C.rop Jiil^:r-5.LlLl:-ilil2lLiU._C££ta^j,\i£a.. A report prep.?..-";d for ths U,S, AID /.ission in Cos ra Rica, Hiy.'^i: ISb/, 69, U.-ii v^^rsidad '_r^^) cultivated in Mexico." Re vista d e f- o c i e d a d 0 u i iT' i c a Mexicapa , 5 i'-i) : 1 29- 1 3 1 . 1961. Fro.Ti B'ioiO;^ i cai Abs traTts , " ill: Ikh^k. 71. \U^rqai. Vaglio, Oscar and Jose Alberto Torres, E;. tudio Prel inii nar ce Sua I os_ _de 1 a Reg ion Occidental de ]a Meseta Central , B o i e t in T-^cTiTco No. 22, M.AJ. San Jos^''. Cost'a Rica; 1953. 72. Weiss, E, A. "Dwarf Castor." V/orld Crops. 18 (12): '+3-^9. December, I9S6. 73' Wellnian, FreQS''ick L. Coffee: Bojany Cul_ti vat ion and Utjliza- t i on , London: Leonard~Tri 1 1 Limited, I96I. Jk. Wei ton, Richard S. "El Salvador Plans Crop Diversification to Spur its Economy." Foreign Agriculture, 5 (32): 5-6. August 7, 1967. 75. Wilson, Dai ton L, ^'Guatemal a--and Its Flourishing Rubber Industry." Foreign Agricul ture, 5 (29): 3-h. July 1/, 1967. B!0CRAPH1C'\L SKETCH John Lc'.7i5 3iebar vjea born August 13, 193^^'; ai Lafayett-?, Indiana. He are\; up on d. csne-.Tl pui'poss fann neas Lafayette end graduated fro.r, Buv'k C: itc-k Hi'jh School in '195'i-- Hf: then attended Pur'due University v;herc; he received the degree of Baciiolor of Science in Agricuiturs I r. June, 195", vvith a major in Agronorr.y. He entered the Graduate School of Kansos State University in SepteT.her, '35S, ar.d received the degree of Master of Science in June-, i9£'0, vvi Lh a niojor in Agronomy and a minor in Agricultural LccnO'n.'cs, I ", r . s I e t r •ierved in the United States Air Force, He entered the G'Jiduare School of trie University of Florida in January, 19c-;, He- left the University in May, 19^5, and farmed cwo years in Indiana. In September, I966, he returned to the University of Florida and conrin'jed vjork LOi'jard the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in Agricultural Eco.-,o, ;! ci In July, 1967, Hr. Bieber began research under the U. 3, A!D/ University of Florida Contract in Costa P.ica. He receiv-^d an interi,-i staff position in November, I5S8, v;i th the University of Florida in or . ■ This d i sier Lit! on was prepared under the direcuoo oF the chair- ir.ar. of the carididnte's supervisory corrimittee Bnd hss bc-eri approved by o]] [^'wrnbers of th-Ji. cornmittea. It v:3'i suiDiiii tttd to the Dean of the College of Agriculture and to the Gr-iduate Council, and was approved as partial fulfillment of the requi reinsn ts for th& decree of Doctor of Pni looophy, March, 1970 ^t>'De5n, College of Agriculture Dear,, Grades ''c- School buper Visory t-omni itee; Jj..Ali.:)lL':x]^h:!±:. Ihe ! I' nan 7/bV-Y