LARGE AND SMALL HOLDINGS CAMBRIDGE UNIVERSITY PRESS FETTER LANE, E.G. C. F. CLAY, MANAGER «Wn!nirfl!): 100, PRINCES STREET Berlin: A. ASHER AND CO. IriWig: F. A. BROCKHAUS #rto gork: G. P. PUTNAM'S SONS Bombaj auto Calcutta: MACMILLAN AND CO., LTD. All rights reserved LARGE AND SMALL HOLDINGS A STUDY OF ENGLISH AGRICULTURAL ECONOMICS BY HERMANN LEVY, PH.D. PROFESSOR IN THE UNIVERSITY OF HEIDELBERG TRANSLATED BY RUTH KENYON WITH CONSIDERABLE ADDITIONS BY THE AUTHOR Cambridge : at the University Press 191 1 TO THE MEMORY OF MY FRIEND ARTHUR WILSON-FOX, CB. BY WHOSE EARLY DEATH ENGLISH AGRICULTURE HAS LOST ONE WHO HAD ITS PROSPERITY AT HEART PREFACE THE German edition of this book appeared in I9O41. When the Cambridge University Press decided to publish the present translation I realised that it would be necessary to add a considerable amount of supplementary matter. In the historical part of the book it was desirable to notice the publications of the six intervening years on the question of the decay of the yeomanry, although they have not altered my views as to the causes of the disappearance of that class. But above all it was necessary to take the Small Holdings Act of 1908 into consideration. I therefore went to England in the summer of 1910 in order to study its working on the spot, so far as it has gone at present. The statistics have been brought up to 1909 so far as was possible. The appendix on " The Modern Small Holder " did not appear in the German edition. It is an attempt briefly to outline some new impressions received as to the psychological aspects of the small holdings question. My personal study of the question was of course mainly made in the course of 1903, when I spent six months touring rural England with this end in view. It is a pleasant duty to offer my warm thanks here to all those who so kindly helped me with information. It is not possible to name them all, for if they were numerous in 1903, they were still more numerous in 1910. But it was a pleasure to find when I came back to England in 1910 that no one had forgotten me, and I am proud to have had personal experience of the English loyalty so well known in Germany. It was sad to miss my old and valued friend Arthur Wilson-Fox, C.B., so early and 1 It was published under the title Entstehung und Ruckgang des landwirtschaftlickc* Grossbetriebs in England, by Julius Springer, Berlin. I owe my thanks to Messrs Springer for giving their consent to the translation. vi Preface suddenly carried off by death from his work for rural England. I would offer my special thanks for the trouble they have taken on behalf of myself and my work to Mr Henry Rew, Major P. G. Craigie and Mr L. J. Cheney of the Board of Agriculture ; to Mr R. A. Yer- burgh, M.P., Mr H. W. Wolff and Mr J. Nugent Harris of the Agricultural Organisation Society ; to the Earl of Ancaster, Mr G. E. Lloyd-Baker, Lord Brassey and Mr H. C. Fairfax-Cholmeley among landowners ; and among gentlemen who have helped me in the most friendly way by information of various kinds, to Mr E. O. Fordham, Mr Montagu Fordham, Sir Gilbert Parker, M.P., Mr Josiah Wedgwood, M.P., Mr G. P. Gooch, and Sir F. A. Channing. The title may seem to be somewhat too comprehensive, and to go beyond what is actually the chief point contained in the material utilised in the book. But I would plead in its justification that there are unfortunately no English works treating of the history and organi- sation of agriculture as they are treated in the German systems of Agrar-Politik : and that though the proper subject of the present volume is the economics of large and small holdings, I have so often had occasion to go outside its strict limits that it seemed desirable to indicate the fact in the title. My intention, however, was to work out this special problem of agricultural economy on the broadest possible lines. For the history of the developments in regard of the unit of agricultural holding in England during the last hundred and fifty years can only be understood when looked at upon the back- ground of the whole contemporary agricultural situation ; and a clear statement of the question as it stands at the present day can only be made when every important fact of rural life in modern England has been taken into consideration. HERMANN LEVY HEIDELBERG February 1911 CONTENTS PART I THE DEVELOPMENT OF THE LARGE FARM SYSTEM AND THE DECAY OF THE SMALL HOLDING CHAP. PAGE INTRODUCTORY i I. The Agricultural Revolution of the Eighteenth Century and the Period of the Continental System 3 II. The Period of the Corn- Laws 45 III. From the Abolition of the Corn-Laws to the Development of Foreign Competition 55 a. The Agricultural History of the First Thirty Years of Free Trade 55 6. The Continued Extension of the Large Farm System . 61 c. The Geographical Distribution of Holdings .... 67 d. Contemporary Views and Theories 69 PART II THE ECONOMICS OF LARGE AND SMALL HOLDINGS AT THE PRESENT DAY IV. The Alteration in Market Conditions and its Effect on Production . 75 V. The Unit of Holding under the New Conditions .... 88 VI. The Economic Aspects of the Revival of Small Farming . . 101 VII Social and Political Aspects of the Problem 114 a. Small Holdings as a Remedy for the Rural Exodus . . 114 b. The Problem of Landownership in relation to the Unit of Holding 118 viii Contents CHAP. PAGE VIII. Legislative Action in Favour of Small Holdings . . . .125 a. The Small Holdings Acts 125 b. The Working of the Act of 1907 147 IX. The Respective Economic Advantages of the Large and Small Holding . . . . . . . . . .154 Introductory ........... 154 A. In relation to the various branches of Agriculture . . 156 a. Corn-Production . . . . * . . .156 b. Vegetable and Fruit Growing . , . . . .162 c. Stock Farming ......... 168 (1) Cattle-breeding . . . . . . . 168 (2) Dairying 172 (3) Pig-keeping 178 (4) Poultry-keeping 178 (5) Pedigree Stock-breeding . . . . . .179 d. Summary and Conclusions 180 B. General Advantages and Disadvantages . . . .183 X. Agricultural Co-operation 187 XI. Historical Retrospect and Present Outlook 200 APPENDIX I. The modern Small Farmer and the Question of Home Colonisation: a Problem of Sociology . . . .214 APPENDIX II. Statistics relating to the Geographical Distribution of Large and Small Farms 223 APPENDIX 1 1 1. List of Authorities quoted 230 INDEX 243 Journal R. A. S.= Journal of the Royal Agricultural Society of England. Report of 1 88 1 = Report of the Royal Commission on the Depressed Condition of the Agricultural Interest, 1880-2. Small Holdings Report, 1889= Report from the Select Committee on Small Holdings, 1889. Report of 1 894 ** First (Second, etc.) Report of the Royal Commission on the subject of Agricultural Depression, 1894-7. Final Report = Final Report of the Royal Commission on the subject of Agri- cultural Depression, 1894-7. Small Holdings Report, 1906= Report of the Departmental Committee ap- pointed by the Board of Agriculture and Fisheries to enquire into the subject of Small Holdings in Great Britain, 1906. PART I THE DEVELOPMENT OF THE LARGE FARM SYSTEM INTRODUCTORY THE question as to the best unit of agricultural management has been of increasing importance in England for the last twenty years. Up to about 1880 it seemed that the last word on the matter had already been spoken. The system of the large farm had made con- tinual progress ever since the middle of the eighteenth century. It was held to be the characteristic, and in fact the only appropriate, method of English agriculture. It had been preached with enthusiasm by the agricultural authorities of the eighteenth century, and those of the nineteenth had taken over and developed the same doctrine. Moreover, throughout the whole period from 1750 to 1880 the doctrine seemed to be entirely justified by the facts of agricultural development. Even as late as between 1850 and 1880 large farms proved to be increasing at the expense of small farms. So that from the point of view of economic policy the superiority of the large holding, so far as regarded English agriculture, seemed to be a fact which there was little, if any, inclination to dispute. Nor did the matter look very different from the point of view of social policy. The large farm certainly did not offer any obvious socio-political advantages. But those who depreciated it as com- pared with the small holding found that their arguments sank into insignificance beside the actual facts of agricultural management. The economic and technical superiorities of the large farm out- weighed all that could be advanced in favour of the smaller unit. From about 1880 onwards these conditions were altered. Large farms no longer increased in number; they rather decreased. On 2 Large and Small Holdings the other hand it began to be evident that small and medium holdings were on the increase. Soon the dogma of the infallibility of the system of the large farm ceased to be altogether convincing. The whole economic theory of the unit of management, which had culminated in the glorification of the large farm, was upset. The astonishing change of tendency began to be investigated, and in many cases small farming, in view of the new conditions, was praised as vehemently as large farming had been before. Meantime those who had always regarded the matter as one of social policy saw that their day had come. Now that they could base their argument on the increasing capacity for economic survival shown by the small farm, they were able to obtain a hearing when they pointed out its socio-political superiority. Thus new life was given to the somewhat arid discussion as to the proper size of the agricultural holding. Into this discussion, however, the present enquiry does not profess to enter. For what has been shown by the discussion, not only in England but also elsewhere, is the necessity for a historical study of the question. Just as formerly the case for the large farm was one-sidedly maintained because men allowed themselves to be dazzled by the facts that were before their eyes, so now the small holding is often championed with equal one-sidedness, because deductions are drawn as to general laws from impressions given by present conditions. The changes, and the causes of the changes, in English systems of land management can only be understood if the history of agriculture is studied, so as to show how modern conditions have come into existence. The first step in this direction is to describe the conditions which brought about the development and preponderance of the large holding in England. Although, as has been seen, the system of the large farm has ceased to extend its boundaries, it is still predominant in English agriculture : England is still a country of large farms. Of the total acreage under cultivation, 42 per cent, is in holdings of 100 to 300 acres, 30 per cent, is in holdings of 300 to over 1000 acres, and only 28 per cent, in holdings of i to 100 acres. Our problem is to explain this preponderance of large and medium holdings. The key to the problem will be found in the agricultural history of the eighteenth century. CHAPTER I THE AGRICULTURAL REVOLUTION OF THE EIGHTEENTH CENTURY AND THE PERIOD OF THE CONTINENTAL SYSTEM LONG before the eighteenth century there had been a period when large farms were formed in great numbers, namely in the middle of the fifteenth century, when the growing profits of sheep- breeding led landlords to buy up small peasant properties and throw them together into a few large farms. But it would be a mistake to suppose that it was at this period that the modern system of the large farm originated. The large holdings then formed were of quite a different kind from those of the nineteenth century and the present day. They were pasture-farms serving for sheep-breeding and the production of wool. The origin of the modern large farm is to be traced to the time when corn-growing flourished. On it were worked out the great modern improvements in the art of corn-cultivation. It is even doubtful whether the large farms of the fifteenth century were not transformed again into small holdings in the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries, which certainly saw a reaction in favour of small farming1. At any rate it is clear that in the first half of the eighteenth century there still remained a great number of small and very small holdings. Moreover when in the second half of the century the rapid consolidation of small holdings into large farms began, the indigna- tion which broke out and the importance ascribed to the movement point to the conclusion that till that time no tendency to increase the size of farms had been noticeable. These small holdings of the eighteenth century were of various classes. In the first place we have very small plots, some of whose holders were also owners, some tenants of a landlord or sub-tenants under a farmer. In any case they were for the most part labourers as well as occupiers ; working for such neighbouring larger farmers as might at times need the services of day-labourers to supplement the 1 J. Rae, Why have the Yeomanry perished? in Contemporary Review, Vol. XLIV, 1883, p. 94. 4 Large and Small Holdings work of their farm-servants. They had before them good hope of rising by industry and thrift to the position of a small farmer properly so called1. The disappearance of this class of landholding day- labourers is a constant subject of complaint with the social reformers of the late eighteenth and early nineteenth centuries2. The next class of small cultivators was that of the small farmer proper, which was still a numerous one in the eighteenth century. The whole time of the small farmer and his family was given to the cultivation of his own holding, and the sale of its produce was their sole source of income. Very close to these little farmers stood the small proprietors, the honest, industrious yeomanry whose disappearance is still lamented by students of agricultural life3. Dr Rae has clearly shown that a large number of them still existed in the middle of the eighteenth century4. How they came to lose their land will be seen later. As a rule this class too employed little outside labour, and very little day-labour. They themselves did the work of the farm with the assistance of their own families. Their holdings would seldom exceed 100 acres. Their yearly income in Cumberland, the classic country of the small owner, ranged from £5 to £$os. All these three classes were alike in one point ; they all had some rights of common. The smallest occupiers profited most by these. They drove their stock on the common pasture6, and gathered wood and furze on the common and waste7; so that to them their common rights were a very important privilege. Agricultural writers of the second half of the eighteenth century give some data as to the commodities produced and sent to market by these small cultivators. The holders of the smallest plots practically never sold corn. They themselves consumed what amount they grew, which was seldom sufficient even to cover their own demand for bread. Their 1 Report of the Royal Commission on the Employment of Women and Children, 1868, \ *5>- • E.g. David Da vies, The Case of Labourers in Husbandry, 1795, p. 56; and The Labourers' Friend, 1835, P- 3- 1 G. F. Eyre, Small Farming, Oxford, 1902, p. 18. 4 Cp. Rae, loc. cit. pp. 546 ff. • R. H. L. Palgrave, Diet, of Political Economy, 1899, p. 685 a; and G. C. Brodrick, English Land and English Landlords, 1881, p. 20. • W. Hashach, English Agricultural Labourer, 1908, pp. 89 ff. and isoff. ; and R. E. Prothero, Pioneers and Progress of English Farming, 1888, passim. 7 Report on the Employment of Women and Children, 1868, loc. cit. Agricultural Revolution 5 pigs and cows were also often destined only to supply their own tables with meat and milk1. Whatever else they needed was paid for out of the wages they earned when working outside their own hold- ings. Anything which they did produce over and above what they consumed themselves consisted in live-stock or its products. Some of them kept two or three cows, two or three pigs, geese and poultry, "according as they may have had success2." The other small holders too, whether proprietors or farmers, had for their main object the production not of corn but of live-stock. It is very difficult to tell on what sized holding, at that time, the pro- duction of corn for the market began. Arthur Young, in 1772, describes the production on a small holding of twelve acres as follows3. Enough wheat would be grown to provide the family with bread-corn for the year. The surplus produce, which would come to market, would be (i) in the first place dairy produce ; (2) an acre of barley, assuming that the occupier fed no pigs ; (3) the sow's annual litter, say ten on the average, of which eight would be sold ; (4) two acres of turnips or pease ; and (5) the poultry that were reared. But corn-growing was not a prominent feature even on such small holdings as did send a little to market, either habitually or after a specially good harvest. Even the most impassioned defenders of the little cultivators did not attempt to claim this for them. On the contrary, some of them admit that as a consequence of the large families of the small holders and their often imperfect methods of cultivation, only a very small quantity of that important article was sold by them4. But they go on to point out the branches of production in which the small holdings did excel : from them came quantities of beef and mutton, pigs and poultry, fruit and vegetables, eggs, butter and milk5. 1 Stephen Addington, An Enquiry into the Reasons for and against enclosing Open Fields, 2nd ed. Coventry, 1772, p. 33: — "Their land furnishes them with wheat and barley for bread, and in many places with beans or peas to feed a hog or two for meat ; with the straw they thatch their cottage, and winter their cow, which gives a breakfast and supper of milk, nine or ten months in the year, for their families." 3 A Political Enquiry into the Consequences of enclosing Waste Lands, 1785, p. 44. 3 Political Essays, 1772, pp. 88 f. 4 J. Donaldson, Modern Agriculture, Edinburgh, 1795, Vol. I, p. 408. 9 F. Forbes, The Improvement of Waste Lands, 1778, p. 153 : — "The occupiers of small and middling farms keep cows upon each of them, which enables them to keep hogs in proportion; young store also and poultry ; and hence the markets and neighbourhood are supplied with butter, cheese, milk, pigs, veal, fowls and eggs." See also J. Duncumb, A General View of the Agriculture of Herefordshire, 1805, p. 34 : — " If they (the small fanners) supplied the public markets with so much less corn as the increased demand of their families required, they made amends in an increased supply of veal, Iamb, poultry and butter." 6 Large and Small Holdings Other representatives of the same side say nothing at all about corn- growing, but they too dwell on the live-stock of the small farms and their success in the lesser branches of agricultural production1. It thus appears that Arthur Young and other champions of the spreading system of the large farm were justified in describing the corn-growing on the small holdings as behind the times. Instead of contradicting them, their opponents point to the superiority of the small farmer over the large in the production of vegetables, butter, milk, pigs, poultry, fruit and so forth. Even at that time, therefore, these pro- ducts were the domain of the small cultivator ; and even in the eighteenth century the products of large and small farming were seen to differ. The large farmers neglected both live-stock and the smaller matters of agriculture in favour of corn-growing. The writers of the period frequently note that the farmer's interest in corn-growing increases as the size of his farm increases, while on large holdings all other branches of production, with the possible exception of sheep- breeding, are neglected2. The care demanded by live-stock and the lesser matters which occupied the attention of the small holders seemed to the large farmer to be troublesome and not very profitable3. The work on an arable farm could be done by day-labourers with superintendence only on the part of the occupier. Live-stock and market-gardening required intensive work, and care and attention such as could not be obtained from hired labour, but which the small cultivator and his family bestowed to admiration4. This was not only claimed by the friends of small farming. Even Arthur Young, who had as a rule so little to say in its favour, was astonished and delighted by the energy of the Lincolnshire peasants, who, as he said, "turned sand into gold5." The care bestowed by the cottagers on their cows was always an object of special commendation. They were in the stable till late at . J Nathaniel Kent, Hints to Gentlemen of Landed Property, 1775, P- Iia- J. S. Girdler, Observations on the Pernicious Consequences of Forestalling, Regrating and Engrossing, 1800, p. 42. The author speaks of men who possess "little farms," or some- times only "cottages with small enclosures," "who gain a livelihood and support large families by selling their sweet little mutton, and their calves, pork, pigs, geese, and other poultry; butter, and eggs." Nothing is said of their growing any corn. J See e.g. Th. Wright, A Short Address to the Public cm the Monopoly of Small Farms, 1795> P- 6 : — " The wealthy farmer's attention is engrossed by the means of producing the greatest quantity of grain and hay." 3 Cp. e.g. Sketth of a Plan for reducing the present High Price of Corn, 1772, p. 16 ; and Adam, Practical Essays on Agriculture, 1789, Vol. II, p. 510. 4 Forbes, op. cit. p. 157; and Kent, op. cit. p. 214. 8 Young, A General View of the Agriculture of Lincolnshire, 1799, pp. 17 ff. Agricultural Revolution 7 night, and so succeeded in making profits out of a branch of farming which appeared to bring little advantage when pursued on a large scale1. Later, as the small cultivators disappeared, writers frequently noticed that the large farmer simply would not be troubled with trifles like butter, poultry and so forth, and that his wife was much too fine to go to market, like the wife of the small farmer, "with a basket of butter, pork, roasting-pigs, or poultry, on her arm3." It was, in fact, not only in the production of meat and the lesser agricultural products that the intensive interest bestowed on the work by the little farmer or cottager seemed to give their holdings the advantage over large farms worked by wage-labour. It was also, and more particularly, in the marketing of such products. Here the wives and daughters of the little landholders played a great part. They themselves took the goods to market, or to their private customers, and their personal business knowledge and interest was a great factor in determining the prices they obtained. The wife of the large farmer was by no means inclined to go to market in person, much less to go round to customers' houses : and the business could hardly be entrusted to the maid-servants3. So that here was another reason why the large farmer was disinclined to trouble him- self with dairy produce and the like, which he could not sell off once and for all as he could his corn. It would however be a mistake to suppose that the small farmers of the eighteenth century had produced only for the local market. In spite of the unfavourable transport conditions, it can be shown that in the eighteenth century (though it is true that the authorities belong to the second half of the century) meat, dairy produce and fruit and vegetables were all produced for central markets. Thus Forbes, in 1778, states that to London and other large towns "provisions are drawn from all parts of the country4." So, for example, London drew its butter mainly from Yorkshire, 1 So e.g. T. Comber, Real Improvement in Agriculture, 1771, p. 40. 8 Girdler, op. cit. p. 29. 8 One writer says that the wives of the small cultivators regarded the poultry and other lesser branches of production as entirely their concern. See A Sketch of a Plan, etc. p. 16. So also C. Vancouver, A General View of the Agriculture of Devonshire, 1808, p. i n : — "It is bat common justice to say, that the industry and attention to business of the farmers' wives and daughters, with the neatness displayed in all their market-ware, at Exeter and in other large towns, are subjects deserving the highest praise. No labour or fatigue is spared in reaching the market in time, be the distance what it may ; nor will any severity of weather prevent them from their ordinary attendance." And Kent, op. cit. p. 113 : — " His (the large farmer's) wife... will not condescend to attend the market like the wives, and children, of little farmers." 4 Forbes, op. cit. p. 153. 8 Large and Small Holdings Dorsetshire and Ireland ; only a small proportion was supplied by Norfolk, Cambridgeshire and Essex1. London was the great market for poultry. Turkeys came to it from Suffolk, geese from Lincolnshire, etc.2 Butter was sent in tubs weighing 56 Ibs. from the small farms of Cumberland to far distant counties3. Westmorland, Durham, Yorkshire, Lincolnshire, Derbyshire, Shropshire and other counties contributed to supply Lancashire with beef and mutton4. Gloucester- shire sent fat oxen, sheep, pigs and cheese to London3. There was even a certain division of labour as between the various counties. Thus Kent, the garden of England, even then supplied the northern counties with fruit6. Cheshire sent large quantities of its cheese to London7. London's demand for eggs, which even then is described as being very large, was not supplied by the neighbouring counties, but by some of those at a distance8. Thus it appears that the means of transport were sufficiently good to open up central as well as local markets to the agriculturists. The improvements made in the roads9, and the extension of the network of canals10, in the course of the century, of course contributed to this end. With the rapid increase of population from the beginning of the century11, the increasing wealth of the various classes and the im- proving means of communication, the profits of the small holders seemed secure. Corn prices, in the first half of the century, were low. In the period 1692 to 1715 the average price of wheat, according to the Eton tables, was 45^. Sd. In the next fifty years it was only 34^. I id?.12 1 J. Middleton, A General View of the Agriculture of Middlesex, 1798, p. 527. 2 Donaldson, op. cit. Vol. n, pp. 150 ff. 3 J. Bailey and G. Culley, A General View of the Agriculture of Northumberland, 3rd ed. 1813, p. 244. 4 Hasbach, op. cit. p. 54. 6 T. Rudge, A General View of the Agriculture of Gloucestershire, 1807, p. 370. 8 Bailey and Culley, op. cit. p. 123. 7 H. Holland, A General View of the Agriculture of Cheshire, 1808, p. 343. 8 Donaldson, op. cit. Vol. II, p. 150. 9 Forbes, op. cit. pp. 153 f. 10 The importance of the canal system, and of shipping generally, for the transport of agricultural produce to the great markets, increased extraordinarily in the eighteenth century. Cp. Arthur Young's admiring words in A Six Weeks' Tour through the Southern Counties, Dublin, 1768, p. 229; and also Forbes, op. cit. p. 154. For the extension of the canal system in the eighteenth century see H. G. Thompson, The Canal System of England, 1902, pp. 8-10. u The population increased from 5,400,000 in the year 1700 to 8,600,000 in 1790. « Tooke, History of Prices, Vol. I, p. 39. Agricultural Revolution 9 Bread, accordingly, was cheap. Meantime, while this most im- portant article of consumption1 was at a low price, wages were rising considerably. Whereas from 1660 to 1720 a day's wage would on the average buy f of a peck of wheat, from 1720 to 1750 the fall of price and rise of wage were such that a day's wage would purchase a whole pecka. IMs increased purchasing power of wages would naturally mean an increased consumption of agricultural produce on the part of the working classes ; and in fact the social reformers of the end of the century show that it was not only the upper classes who had increased their consumption of meat, butter, eggs and poultry at this period, by their complaint that now, in face of the rise in the price of corn, labourers could no longer afford such articles. The complaints would have no point if the people had not formerly, at the time when corn was cheap, been accustomed to make these animal products an im- portant part of their consumption. Thus it is very natural that nothing should be heard as to diffi- culties of the small farmers in the first half of the eighteenth century. The conditions of the market were favourable for their produce. And the smallest holders, who worked outside their own holdings and did not grow corn enough for their own needs, had the advantage of a high wage, while the price of bread was lower than it had ever been before. The large farmers, whose chief business as a rule was the sale of corn, found their position less satisfactory. This was obviously the result of the fall in the price of corn as compared with the end of the seventeenth century. It was the old story, and one which was often to be heard again. High prices had led to the breaking-up of land hitherto unploughed, and rents had risen. Then, when with good harvests prices fell, the farmers were unable to continue to pay the rents based on the higher prices. Hence between 1715 and 1765 there were frequent complaints from them of distress and from the land- lords of the fall of rents which they had to endure. From 1731 to 1733 and again in the years just after 1740 these complaints are particularly audible. But they always concern only corn-growing and the arable farmer3. 1 Wheaten bread became the most important article of food in the dietary of the labouring classes during this period ; cp. the authorities cited by Tooke, op. cit. p. 60 ; and also M. Peters, The Rational Farmer, 2nd ed. 1771, p. 118. '2 Tooke, op. cit. p. 61. On the rise of wages along with falling corn-prices cp. Adam Smith, Wealth of Nations, 2nd ed. 1817, Vol. I, p. 333; and Thorold Rogers, Work and 1885, p. 121. 1 The causes of agricultural distress at this time may be clearly traced in various publica- io Large and Small Holdings It is natural, again, that under these circumstances there was no question, up to about the year 1765, of any consolidation of small farms. Large farmers who grew corn were not as a rule in any serious distress, but the periods of specially low prices sufficed to prevent any great extension of the area under corn and any general increase in the size of holdings. Although a little later Arthur Young expatiated on the satisfactory results of William Ill's bounty on export1, he only did so because he was desirous of showing that State action could help to keep up prices. Certainly the price of wheat would have fallen still lower if the home market had not been relieved by the export of corn in years of plenty. But even the artificially high price induced by the bounty was too low to bring about any real increase of arable farming, improvement of poor land and the like. Arthur Young himself said in 1774 that he had every reason to believe that agriculture (by which he always means corn-growing) had made practically no progress in the cheap years 1730 to I7562. But a radical change in all these conditions took place in the second half of the eighteenth century. From about the year 1765 to the end of the Napoleonic wars in 1815 prices rose almost unceasingly, and more especially the price of those particular commodities whose cheapness in the first half of the eighteenth century had proved so beneficial to the mass of the population, namely the prices of corn and of bread. From 34^. lid. in the period 1715 to 1765 the price of wheat rose to 45^. yd. in the period 1760 to 1790, and to $$s. i id. in the following decade. From 1805 to 1813 the annual average price was never below 73.?., and often over IOOT. In 1812 it reached 122S. Sd.3 The causes of this great and constantly increasing rise were various. In the first place, the fifty years up to 1765 had been a period of extraordinarily good harvests. According to Tooke, in all that time there were only five bad years4. With the year 1765 this tions. Thus W. Allen, in The Landlords Companion, 1742, p. 13, says that in the prosperous times woodlands and sheep-walks had been turned into ploughland. These would naturally become unprofitable again when prices fell. And even the bounty on export did not prevent this distress, since it was never able to keep the price of wheat at the level which would have been necessary to meet the increased rents of the arable farms. Cp. furthei on this particular point W. Ellis, The Modern Husbandman, Month of December, '743- PP- 96-7 a°d 98-111. Also Tooke, op. cit. pp. 27, 46, 52, and Vol. vi, p. 383-4; and Rogers, op. cit. p. in. 1 Arthur Young, Political Arithmetic, 1774, pp. 29 ff. » Ibid., p. 33. * G. R. Porter, Progress of the Nation, 1851, p. 148. 4 Tooke, op. cit. Vol. I, pp. 39 f. Agricultural Revolution \ \ period of abundance came to an end. Between that year and 1791 there were very few really good harvests1. In the second place, while the home production of wheat was thus decreasing, population was increasing. As a natural consequence, England passed soon after 1750 from the position of a corn-exporting to that of a corn-importing country. But even increasing imports could not reduce the price to the low level of the first half of the century, in view of the growing demand and the lessened home supply. On the contrary, it rose higher and higher. Conditions became still more unfavourable with the outbreak of the French war in 1793. In the period which followed (1792 to 1813) the harvests were quite extraordinarily bad2, while population was still increasing rapidly, viz. by 3,000,000 persons in the twenty years 1790 to 1811. These two circumstances by them- selves would have sufficed to drive up corn-prices, but further the wars, and above all Napoleon's Continental System, hindered and even prevented the necessary regular importation of corn. While an import of about \\ million quarters in 1801 had not been sufficient to stave off dearth and starvation, between 1806 and 1813 the imports never exceeded 400,000 quarters, though the home harvests were most unfavourable3. This conjunction of bad seasons, inadequate im- ports and rapidly growing population seems fully sufficient to explain the rise in prices. The effect of the rise on the mass of the people was terrible. After the good times they had enjoyed in the period of abundance they now found themselves plunged into misery, privation and famine. The increase of population seemed to be a curse. All the progress made in the first half of the eighteenth century was lost again. The very word "labourers" was almost universally replaced by the term " labouring poor." The deterioration in the position of the working classes is especially traceable in the decrease in the purchasing power of wages. It is true that wages did rise with the rise in corn-prices. But that rise was insignificant in face of the fact that the price of provisions generally had risen in a much greater proportion. The nominal wage did indeed increase, but real wages fell lower and lower. Thus according to the figures given by various authorities, the wages of the agricultural labourer rose between 1760 and 1813 by 60 per cent., 1 Tooke, op. cit. pp. 50, 81 f. 3 Ibid., pp. 84 f., 179 ff., 358 ff., 293 ff. 8 Reports respecting Grain and the Corn Laws, November 1814, p. 121. 12 Large and Small Holdings whereas the price of wheat rose by 130 per cent1 This inadequate rise of wages led, as is well known, to the introduction of the allow- ance system, by which the parish bound itself to make up from the poor-rate the amount by which a labourer's wages might fall short of what was necessary to his existence. Wages-scales were established, which regulated the necessary income according to the price of bread2. If the labourer did not earn the ideal wage thus fixed, the "allowance" made up the deficiency. The extent of the claims on this allowance in the period of rising corn-prices is shown by the enormous increase in the poor-rate in the years 1801 to i8n3. Under these conditions the lot of the labouring classes became worse with every decade. The extensive enquiries of Sir Frederick Eden showed how miserable their condition was even as early as I7954. There was universal complaint of the inadequate rise of wages in face of the exorbitant price of bread5, not only in regard of indus- trial workers, or workers in the towns, but also in regard of the agricultural labourers. Even the landed interest, which is seldom in the course of history found objecting to low wages, was obliged to recognise the seriousness of the fall in their purchasing power. Arthur Young, strongest of representatives of this class, admits it6. He did not, however, admit that it was a disadvantage. He took the view that low wages meant more work done, and that therefore the deterioration in the position of the agricultural labourer was rather good than bad. Another writer justified the fall of real wages by saying that "the present high price of wheat being, it is hoped, only temporary,... an advance of wages in the above proportion would 1 For further particulars see H. Levy, Die Not der englischen Landwirte zur Zeit der hohen Getreiilezblle, Stuttgart, 1902, p. 28. In addition to the authorities there quoted see C. D. Brereton, Observations on the Administration of the Poor Laws, 3rd ed. p. 77. 2 Cp. Levy, op. cit. p. 27. 3 Porter, op. cit. p. 90. The poor-rate rose in these ten years by about £2% millions. 4 Sir F. Eden, The State of the Poor, 1797. See Vol. I, p. 404 and passim. 8 E.g. N. Kent, A General View of the Agriculture of Norfolk, Norwich, 1796, p. 173. In 1801, when wheat was at nor. §d. per quarter, the Rev. A. Jobson wrote in the Annals of Agriculture, Vol. xxxvn, p. 33:— "Some farmers now pay their labourers only 9*. a week ; some pay IQJ. 6egun to experience : and a tendency to the engrossing of farms is very observable in the agricultural districts, as well as in those employed in pasturage." Cp. also the example given by Home, op. cit. p. 267. Agricultural Revolution 23 ceeding was the increase of rent1 : and the very reason why this consolidation of holdings was favoured by so many writers on the subject was that they regarded the rise of rents as the clearest sign of agricultural progress2. Nor was this the only gain to the landowners by the process of "engrossing." At the present day much of the half-heartedness of landlords over the question of small holdings is attributable to the expenses they entail in buildings and repairs. In the eighteenth century the same consideration contributed to quicken the progress of consolidation*. The houses of the small holders were either pulled down or used as dwelling-houses for the day-labourers demanded in increasing numbers by the large farm system4. Very often, especially in the case of the smaller cottages, they were simply allowed to fall to pieces6. At any rate, the expense of repairs was lessened. Indeed, even when the old buildings were still used as labourers' dwellings they often received very little in the way of repairs. When one became altogether uninhabitable, its occupants were simply turned into another, so that finally three or four families would be found inhabiting one of the old farmhouses'. Besides these two advantages to the landlord, namely the increase of rent and the saving in cost of repairs, there was a third in the greater ease with which rent was collected from a few large tenants paying half-yearly, as compared with a large number of small men with smaller capitals and consequently less able to pay regularly7. 1 Davis, Wiltshire, p. 24: — "The great object of consolidating farms is an increase of rent." 2 Billingsley, op. cit. p. 156 : — "Let me ask the advocates for small farms, what occasioned that consolidation of them, which they so much reprobate Was it not because the large holders could afford to give more rent than the small? " 8 Young, Farmer's Letters, pp. 119-20 : and Forbes, op. cit. p. 151. 4 Report on Small Holdings, 1889, qu. 4032, and also qu. 6983. 5 Strickland, op. cit. p. 42 : — " It is much to be regretted, that the practice of suffering cottages to fall to decay, and the disinclination to build new ones, should be so prevalent in this part of the kingdom." Also Vancouver, op. cit. p. 98 : — " In this district the cottages are certainly in a state of alarming decrease." And Perry, op. cit. p. 20 : — "A gentleman... informed me, that in his native parish in Cambridgeshire, in 1803, forty-three fires were extinguished, and as many comfortable cottages demolished, to each of which from two to ten acres of land were attached, in order that a farm of 200 acres might be doubled in size." 8 Vancouver, op. cit. p. 94. 7 Forbes, op. cit. pp. 151-2; and Kent, op. cit. p. 206. AlsoW. Pennington, Reflections on the various advantages resulting from the draining, inclosing and allotting of large commons, etc., 1769, p. 56. He sums up the reasons thus: — "Engrossers generally give more rent, and want less allowed, if anything at all, for repairs." Large and Small Holdings Accordingly the tendency among landowners was increasingly in favour of the enlargement of the size of holding. But they also looked about them to see if it were not possible to obtain control of more land and so to form more of these very profitable large farms. The open fields, mostly held in small holdings, and above all the common pastures, presented themselves as possible objects of this transformation. With the profits of pasture-farming decreasing and the importance of corn-growing increasing it seemed to be desirable from an economic point of view to turn the commons into wheat- fields and to put both them and the open-field strips at the disposal of progressive individuals. Nor was it very difficult for the great landowners to effect this, since they were almost always the chief owners of land and chief holders of common rights in any given parish, or at any rate, by purchasing land, they could if they wished become so1. The increase in the number of Enclosure Acts in the course of the eighteenth century illustrates the rapidity with which the division of the commons and the consolidation of the open-field holdings proceeded. Between 1702 and 1760 only 246 Acts were passed, affecting about 400,000 acres. In the next fifty years the Acts reached the enormous total of 2438, and affected almost five million acres2. The immediate result of the enclosures was a further disappear- ance of small holders. The enclosures took place at the instance of the landlords with a view to the enhancement of rents3, and therefore to the formation of large holdings to be let to the corn-producing large farmer. This was accordingly the usual consequence of a Bill of Enclosure. The first to disappear were the landholding day-labourers or cottiers. These received no land in consideration of their common rights unless they could actually prove them : very often their claims were altogether disregarded. But even in cases where they did receive a small allotment, they could not maintain their position. The scrap of land they received was not sufficient to feed a cow ; nor had they the capital with which to do the necessary fencing. There was nothing for it but to sell their bit of ground4. The buyer was 1 Cp. Hasbach, op. cit. pp. 61 ff. and rio. 8 Cp. Levy, op. cit. p. 127. * Cp. Hasbach, op. cit. p. 56. 4 Cp. the General Report on Enclosures, 1808, pp. 55 f. Thus, as to the parish of Alconbury :— " Many kept cows that have not since (the enclosure) : they could not enclose, Agricultural Revolution 25 as a rule the landlord, and the allotment went to enlarge the holding of the large farmer1. But though the cottier class was the first to go, the ruin of the small holders proper, whether owners or tenants, went forward equally surely, if more slowly. The commons had been quite as fundamental a condition of their existence as of that of the cot- tiers. Everywhere, on the conclusion of an enclosure, they fell into distress. Many "starved with their families, till necessity forced them to quit their farms1": and it was the general opinion that "strip the small farms of the benefit of the commons, and they are all at one stroke levelled with the ground*." The small farmers were not in a position to compensate the landlord for the expenses of enclosure by paying a higher rent. On the contrary, they found it difficult to continue to pay the old amount; for they had no longer free pasture for their stock, and besides, the land allotted to them was not enough to enable them to keep as many beasts as formerly4. Meantime the landlord had every motive for forming large arable holdings. While he could not hope to get a high rent from his smaller tenants he knew that their land, if let to a few large farmers, would bring in ever-increasing profits. In some cases a large farmer, on replacing several small ones, would not only offer ten times the rent they had paid, but would also take on himself the cost of the enclosure5. and sold their allotments. Left without cows or land." Of Parndon, in Essex : — " Their little allotments all sold ; could not enclose " : and so of many others. Arthur Young mentions in the Annals, Vol. xxxvi (1801) innumerable cases in which the poor had lost their cows after enclosure. 1 The writer of the General Report on Enclosures says (pp. 12 f.) : — "In many cases the poor had unquestionably been injured. In some cases... where allotments were assigned, the cottagers could not pay the expense of the measure, and were forced to sell their allotments. In others, they kept cows by right of hiring their cottages, or common rights, and the land going of course to the proprietor, was added to the farms, and the poor sold their cows." Cp. the Letter of the Earl of Winchilsea in Communications, op. cit. Vol. I, p. 80 : — " I am sorry to say, that I am afraid most of those cottages were taken away at the time of the several enclosures, and the land thrown to the farms " ; and p. 84 : — " Whoever travels through the midland counties, and will take the trouble of enquiring, will generally receive for answer, that formerly there were a great many cottagers who kept cows, but that the land is now thrown to the farmers." Cp. also J. Farey, A General View of the Agriculture of Derbyshire, 1815, p. 76. 2 The Advantages and Disadvantages of enclosing Waste Lands, 1772, p. 36. 3 An Enquiry into the Advantages and Disadvantages resulting from Bills of Enclosure, 1780, p. 14. * Hasbach, op. cit. p. 109. 8 J. Monk, A General View of the Agriculture of Leicestershire, p. 45, says for example that the parish of Queniborough had been let before enclosure for is. 6d. an acre ; but a gentleman 26 Large and Small Holdings Naturally, therefore, the landlords as a rule followed up enclosure by " engrossing1." Small farmers, whose families had in many cases occupied the open-field holdings for centuries, disappeared in hun- dreds2. Their fate was shared by the small freeholders and copy- holders, who had also held a large number of the old type of holdings. They did not perhaps feel the effects of enclosure quite so directly as the tenant-farmers, who were simply given notice to quit by their landlords. The yeoman class could not suffer in the same way by a demand for increased rent on the competition of a large farmer bidding higher for the land they occupied. But they were equally touched by the economic difficulties entailed on small holders by the enclosures. The disappearance of the commons, for instance, was a great blow to them8. Again, they had not the capital necessary for fencing4. For this purpose many of them borrowed money from the large landowners, and so became indebted to their richer neigh- bours. Very soon they found themselves unable to keep up the payment of the interest due : and thereupon they sold their land to their creditor, "whose sole view at first setting out was to get the land of the whole parish into his own hands5." So soon as any parish came wholly into the hands of one landlord, he of course turned out the small holders and replaced them by large farmers'. There had declared that he would give 25.?. an acre and take the expenses of enclosure on himself if he might have a lease of 100 acres for twenty-one years. 1 J. Donaldson, A General View of the Agriculture of Northamptonshire, 1794, p. 60, says that after the enclosures " several of those who occupy small farms must necessarily be re- moved, in order to enable the proprietors to class the lands into farms of a proper size." See also The Advantages and Disadvantages, pp. 7 f. , for a description of the effect on the village community : — " The landowner, seeing the great increase of rent made by his neighbour, conceives a desire of following his example; the village is alarmed ;... the small farmer dreads that his farm will be taken from him to be consolidated with the larger ; the cottager ...expects to lose his commons." Cp. also Essays on Agriculture occasioned by reading Mr Stone's Report, 1796, p. 74 : — "When the commoners happen to be only tenants, which is frequently the case, the landlord, on enclosing, not uncommonly turns several of them out, to convert his smaller divisions into large farms." 2 Even the General Report, though in favour of the enclosures, admits (p. 32) that — "there is, however, one class of farmers which have undoubtedly suffered by enclosures ; for they have been greatly lessened in number: these are the little farmers." Cp. also T. Batchelor, A General View of the Agriculture of Bedford, p. 25 : — " It is evident that the prevalence of the enclosing system, and other causes, have diminished the number of farms within the last fifty years to a considerable amount." 3 General Report on Enclosures, p. 158. 4 Addington, op. cit. p. 35 : — "When their fields are enclosed, not a few of these small proprietors are obliged to sell their land, because they have not money to enclose it." 8 Cursory Remarks on Enclosures, 1786, pp. 6-7. 6 F. Moore, Considerations on the exorbitant Price of Provisions, 1773, p. « : — "In Agricultural Revolution 27 was an actual persecution of small owners, whose land was often practically stolen from them. The commissioners of enclosure well understood how to manage matters in the interests of the great land- lords, so for instance that the land allotted to the small proprietors should lie as far as possible from their houses and farm buildings. The consequent increased expenses of cultivation did away with their small margin of profit1. The little yeomen knew very well what enclosure meant to them. But all their efforts to oppose it were frustrated by the power of the great landlord or the large farmers, who only saw in the abolition of the small proprietors an opportunity for increasing the land in their own hands2. But while these numerous individuals were being ruined by the division of the commons and consolidation of the open-field holdings, extraordinary progress resulted on the economic side. From that point of view, enclosures and engrossing were only a means by which corn-growing was brought to yield the highest possible profits, and by improved methods of cultivation increasing quantities were pro- duced to meet the increasing prices. Whereas Anderson regarded commons and " wastes " as one and the same thing3, the old village pastures were now broken up by the large farmers, and in many cases turned into excellent wheat-fields. Thus Arthur Young speaks of the sandy tracts of Norfolk, Suffolk and Nottinghamshire, "which yield corn and mutton and beef from the force of enclosure alone"; and of the Lincolnshire wolds, "which from barren heaths at \s. per acre are by enclosure alone rendered profitable farms4." It is true that some writers, opponents of the enclosures and the large farm system, attempted to show that the enclosures had led to an exten- sion of pasture-farming6, and so to condemn the movement from a passing through a village near Swaffham, in the county of Norfolk, a few years ago, to my great mortification I beheld the houses tumbling into ruins, and the common fields all enclosed ; upon enquiring into the cause of this melancholy alteration, I was informed that a gentleman of Lynn had bought that township and the next adjoining to it ; that he had thrown the one into three, and the other into four farms ; which before the enclosure were in about twenty farms : and upon my further enquiring what was become of the farmers who were turned out, the answer was, that some of them were dead, and the rest were become labourers." 1 Girdler, op. cit. p. 40. 2 Addington, op. cit. p. 35 ; and Girdler, op. cit. p. 40. 3 Anderson, Essays, Vol. Ill, p. 30. 4 Young, Political Arithmetic, pp. 148 ff. 5 The view that enclosures decreased arable land was mentioned and controverted as a popular argument in an Essay on the Nature and Methods of ascertaining the specific Shares of Proprietors upon the Enclosure of Common Fields, 1766, p. 13. It is to be found in 28 Large and Small Holdings socio-political point of view, as leading to rural depopulation. But they were only able to point to a few counties, such as Leicestershire and Northampton, and some parts of Warwickshire and Huntingdon- shire, where enclosure had occasionally led to a lessening of the area under corn. These cases were, as Arthur Young pointed out, fast diminishing exceptions ; and in the whole north and east of the country enclosures were almost invariably followed by an extension of arable. It can hardly be supposed that pasture-farming would be extended after enclosure when by common admission the aim was everywhere to turn pasture into arable. As the price of corn rose higher this became increasingly desirable, and the enclosures would naturally be used to further it. During the French wars this was so markedly the case that no one any longer attempted to dispute it. There was yet another cause which contributed to the extension of the large farm system. Many social reformers condemned at the time, and many still condemn, the part played by the landlords in the expropriation of the small holders and the division of the com- mons. But it was not only the large landowners, acting in their own interests as capitalists, who brought about this development. The small proprietors too, the independent yeomanry, even where they remained untouched by the effects of enclosure, dealt a deadly blow at the system of small holdings. The extinction of the yeomanry is the clearest illustration of the irresistible force of the economic conditions which were sweeping away the old system of agricultural holdings. In the eighteenth century, and even in the second half of the century, the yeoman class was still numerous. Part of it was indeed Price's Observations on Reversionary Payments, 1773, p. 388, in Cursory Remarks, p. 2, and in An impartial view of English Agriculture, 1766, p. »i. It is more surpnsing to find that Dr Hasbach adopts it (see his History of the Agricultural I^abourer, pp. 369-71). The points which he brings forward in its favour cannot all be recounted here ; but his argument that pasture-farming was more profitable than arable is certainly misleading. Various facts which contradict it have already been mentioned in the text. He notes that Arthur Young makes a calculation directed to show how much larger a profit was obtainable from an acre of pasture than from an acre of arable. But this is easily understood when it is remembered that Young did not share in the general passion for corn-growing, but advocated pasture-farming and mixed husbandry. Dr Hasbach also adduces in favour of his theory the fact that England ceased to export corn in the last quarter of the eighteenth century. But this by no means proves that the production of corn remained stationary, much less that it decreased. The phenomenon is quite sufficiently explained by the growth of population on the one hand and the bad harvests on the other. Other- wise it hardly seems to be doubted now that the enclosures in general, that is to say the enclosures of open fields and commons taken together, increased the area under corn. Cp. A. H. Johnson, The Disappearance of the Small Landowner, Oxford, 1909, pp. 18 f. Agricultural Revolution 29 ruined by the enclosures. But apparently this would only affect these whose properties were very small. The larger proprietors would not be annihilated, nor even seriously injured, either by the division of the commons or by the cost of fencing1. They would safely survive the enclosures. Further, not all the yeoman class even came in contact with the movement. Many held land which had been enclosed long ago. Nevertheless, even those members of the class who had not suffered and could not suffer by the enclosures disappeared in the course of the period 1760-1815. As early as 1770 it began to be said that the yeomanry were vanishing. Arbuthnot, himself a large farmer, gives important evi- dence on this point. He was a champion of the large farm system, and set himself to reply to Price's attacks upon it. But he was obliged to admit the fact of the disappearance of many of the yeoman class, which Price had attributed to the development of large farming; and he wrote : — " I most truly lament the loss of our yeomanry, that set of men who really kept up the independence of this nation ; and sorry I am to see their lands now in the hands of monopolizing lords2." Marshall, writing in the year 1787, also admits the fact8. The reports on the various counties published by the Board of Agriculture between 1790 and 1815 also contain much discussion as to, or notice of, this disappearance4. Of Westmorland, the classic country of the small holder in England, Pringle reported in 1794 that the class was diminishing day by day8. From the most various quarters about this time comes corroborating evidence6. But more significant than any mention of the fact is the light which is thrown on the nature of the process of extinction. The disappearance of small properties in the period 1760-1815 did not always imply deterioration in the personal position of the yeoman himself. Discussions of the subject seldom mention bank- 1 See also Hasbach, op. cit. pp. 107 ff. 2 Arbuthnot, op. cit. p. 139. 3 Marshall, Norfolk, Vol. i, p. 9: — "Formerly the farms were much smaller; but the numerous little places of the yeomanry having fallen into the hands of men of fortune, and being now incorporated with their extended estates, are laid out into farms of such sizes as best suit the interest, or the conveniency, of the present proprietors." 4 See e.g. Thos. Wedge, A General View of the Agriculture of Cheshire, 1794, p. n; R. Brown, A General View etc. of Derby, 1794, p. 14; and Robertson, op. cit. p. 76. 5 A. Pringlfe, A General View of the Agriculture of Westmorland, Edinburgh, 1794, p. 40. 8 E.g. Holland, Cheshire, p. 80 ; R. W. Dickson, A General View etc. of Lancashire, 1814, p. 10 ; The Complete English Farmer, 1807, under the head Yeomen: — "This useful and important class of society has been within these few years considerably lessened. " 30 Large and Small Holdings ruptcy of the yeomen, or that they sold their land in order to take up some inferior occupation, to migrate to the towns, or to leave the country1. Such occurrences became prominent at a later time, namely in the period of the corn-laws. But between 1760 and 1815 they were exceptional. At that time the yeomanry as a rule gave up their land with a light heart They ceased to be small owners in order to become large farmers. There is abundant evidence of this fact2. It is described by Albrecht Thaer, whose knowledge of English agricultural literature was unrivalled. The small owner saw, he says, that the tenant of a large farm was in a better position than himself and made a larger income, and he made up his mind to sell his land, and with the capital so acquired to devote himself afresh to farming, but now as a tenant. This, he continues, was the reason why in certain districts the yeoman class had almost entirely vanished, and only farmers and cottiers were to be found3. Marshall wrote of the Norfolk yeomen " that many, seeing men whom they lately held their inferiors raised by an excessive profit, which had been recently made by farming, became dissatisfied with the homeliness of their situation, and sold their comparatively small patrimonies in order that they might — agreeably with the fashion or frenzy of the day — become great farmers4." Sinclair, too, mentions it as " a well-known fact" that small owners frequently sold their estates in order to become large farmers8. That the yeomen should have found tenant-farming more profitable than working their own land is natural enough under the circumstances of the time. They would feel all the effects of the rising corn-prices as other small holders felt them, with the exception that they did not have to pay increasing rents out of their decreasing profits. They, too, were pasture-farmers and market-gardeners, that is to say were devoted to those branches of farming whose profitableness was 1 Cp. Levy, Der Untergang klein-bduerlicher Betriebe in England, in Conrad's Jahr- biichem, 1903, p. 147. 2 E.g. Th. Stone, Suggestions for rendering the Enclosure of Common Fields a Source of Population and Riches, 1787, pp. 42 f. : — "It has been a common circumstance, in counties where a spirit for improvement in agriculture first broke forth, that the yeomanry, or persons possessed of small estates in their own occupations, have been induced to sell them, to purchase a stock sufficient to improve larger tracts of land, the property of other persons, which they have hired upon improving leases." * A. Thaer, Einleitung zur Kenntniss in die englische Landwirtschaft, Hanover, 1801, Vol. I, pp. 25 f. 4 Cp. Johnson, op. cit. p. 142. 5 Sinclair, Code of Agriculture, 1817, p. 37. Agricultural Revolution 31 decreasing as the profitableness of corn-growing increased. Many of them would be injured as consumers by the rising price of bread and flour, if, as in Lincolnshire, a holding of twenty acres was required to provide the necessary bread for a family in the bad years1. From these causes they would find their profits diminishing, though they might not be ruined. They were not forced to give up their holdings, as were the small tenant-farmers. But year by year they would find it more difficult to keep up their wonted standard of life, and it would appear impossible to improve their position in any way. Thus for example it was reported of the Derbyshire yeoman that " the smaller landowner (provincially "statesman")... finds his mind distracted how to preserve his estate, as well as the rank his father held, and how to improve his fortune on rational principles2." They would look with envy at the flourishing estate of the capitalistic large farmer. They would see how he concentrated on the production of corn, and what increasing profits he drew from the sale of his wheat. They would see how the large farmer and even the tenant of a medium-sized holding came to attain the position of a gentleman, and could enjoy all modern comforts and allow himself all manner of expenditure on luxuries, while they themselves had to work harder than their forefathers for a smaller return. On the other hand, the price of land had risen enormously since 1760. The high corn-prices and the possibility of drawing high rents from arable holdings had produced a positive land-hunger in the upper classes3. The buying and selling of land had become a business in which some speculators succeeded in making thousands of pounds annually4. Even the large farmers often bought to add to the farms they already rented5. At the same time there was an increasing demand for land from persons who wanted to buy estates for the sake of their social and political advantages. The political influence bound up with the ownership of land, and its necessity for purposes of shooting and hunting, all helped to drive up its price even higher than its agricultural value had already made it. Again, it was the ambition of men who had made fortunes in trade or manufacture to raise themselves out of the position of parvenus into 1 Vide supra, p. 17. 2 Brown, Derbyshire, p. 14. 3 See Levy, Die Not etc., pp. 6 ff. 4 R. G. Welford, H and p. 53. Speeches by Richard Cobden, 1870, Vol. I, pp. 30, 151 f., 163 ff. ; F. Engels, Die Lage der arbeitenden Klasscn in England, Leipzig, 1845, pp. 314-317 ; H. Martineau, op. cit. Vol. l, pp. 510 f. ; H. Dunkley, The Charter of the Nations, 1854, pp. 65 ff. ; and especially Walpole, op. cit. VoL IV, PP- 357 ff- * Report on the Handloom Weavers, Reports, Vol. XXIV, Sess. 1840 [636], p. 18. 3 Report of the Statistical Committee appointed by the Anti-Corn Law Conference, p. 18. 4 Report of the great Anti-Corn Law Meeting, 1842, pp. 22 f. For the small consumption of meat see also B. W. Noel, A Plea for the Poor, 1841, p. 3; and Brereton, Wages etc., p. 61. Cp. also the labourers' budgets given by A. Wilson Fox, in Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, 1903, pp. 323-325. » Speeches of R. Cobden, p. 164. * Walpole, op. cit. Vol. iv, p. 363. 48 Large and Small Holdings potatoes among a family of seven," wrote the correspondent of an M.P. in I84I1. The old fare of bread, bacon and beer was frequently replaced by water-gruel, rice and potatoes, and for drink a decoction of boiled tea-leaves2. In spite of all expectations from the peace, therefore, the people found themselves after 1815 not merely in no better position, but perhaps degraded even below the level to which they had already become accustomed. A commercial policy which raised the price of the chief necessary of life and at the same time injured trade and industry produced a worse state of affairs in time of peace than any war could have brought about. The policy did not even profit those in whose interests such a fearful burden was laid on the people at large. The farmers, who were to have reaped the chief advantages of the corn-laws, were in a state of almost continuous distress from 1815 to 1 846s. Meantime the agricultural result of the high duties was to carry still further that one-sided development of arable farming which had been going on since 1760. The Reports of the Committees on the Distressed Condition of Agriculture in 1836-7 prove clearly that pasture- farming and market- gardening not only made no progress during the thirty years of the corn-law period, but even deteriorated4. The rotation of crops, a matter whose importance in relation to pasture-farming had been recognised even in the eighteenth century, was only in use on a com- paratively few model farms. Baker reported on Essex in 1845 that experiments with winter root-crops had been made for the first time in that county a few years previously5. In 1849 the dairy-farms of Suffolk, for which that county had been celebrated in the time of Arthur Young, had practically disappeared6. According to Raynbird's figures, 90 per cent, fewer cows were kept than at that period ; every- where pasture had been turned into arable. "The corn laws... have induced farmers to rely for profit upon a great breadth of wheat, to the neglect of stock-farming and improved systems of husbandry," 1 Hansard, Vol. LIX, p. 759. 2 R. Heath, The English Peasant, 1893, p. 45. 3 Levy, Die Not etc., passim. 4 See especially the evidence of the Scottish fanners. They had introduced the rotation of crops much more commonly than their English neighbours, and one after another expressed their astonishment at the poor methods of breeding and bad agricultural systems of the Englishmen. See e.g. Report on Agriculture, 1837, qu. 13,813 and qu. 14,089. 5 R. Baker, On the Farming of Essex, in Journal of the Royal Agricultural Society, 1835, P-3- 6 W. and H. Raynbird, On the Agriculture of Suffolk, 1849, PP- 7' 94- Corn-law Period 49 wrote an agriculturist in I8431. This must have been at least in part caused by the inability of the mass of the population to consume animal products to any extent worth mentioning. Obviously produc- tion could not extend when the market was continually shrinking. Partly too, however, the corn-duties directly stimulated the production of corn at the expense of other branches of agriculture. They never indeed achieved the end of which the landed interest had dreamed at the time of their introduction. But men are often inclined to forget the facts of the present in favour of their hopes for the future : and the agriculturists acted as if the results they expected from the corn-laws had in reality been achieved. Although neither the tariff of 1815 nor that of 1828 were able to keep the price of corn anywhere near the desired level, yet the farmers behaved as though that high price, which they supposed to be guaranteed, already existed. Wastes and pastures were broken up, and rents, which had risen so enormously since 1760, were not lowered as prices fell, because it was supposed that the duties would bring the price up again2. In bad seasons the artificial limita- tion of imports did in fact produce this rise of price. But in good seasons the increased home production alone sufficed to bring the price of wheat below the level which seemed profitable to the agricul- turist, so that universal lamentation was made over low prices and high rents. Even at such times, however, the idea which was bound up with the maintenance of the corn-laws, namely that some time or other prices would rise again, continued to influence men's minds so powerfully that the area under corn still continued to extend8. This extension of arable in the period 1815 to 1846 was based on an imaginary foundation ; it resulted from an assumption which was never justified. The population at large suffered under it inasmuch as they had to pay more for their bread than the people of other countries. The English farmers got no profit out of the difference in price at home and abroad, but before five different Parliamentary enquiries complained of their distressed condition. Such was the price paid for the artificial stimulation of corn-growing and for the continued extension of the area under wheat at the expense of pasture and other purposes. Two causes thus contributed to maintain the predominance, or it might almost be said the monopoly, of arable farming in English 1 Welford, op. cit. p. 199. 2 Levy, Die Not etc., pp. 76 f. 3 See an exhaustive discussion of the point, with references, in Levy, op. cit. passim, and especially Chapter IV. 50 Large and Small Holdings agriculture after the year 1815. There was, first, a diminished con- sumption of meat and other animal products, and of fruit, vegetables, etc., in consequence of the deteriorated standard of life of the working classes : and secondly, an artificial stimulus was given to the production of corn by the introduction of the high duties. The peace, therefore, produced no change in the direction in which agricultural production was moving. Equally little change appeared in the matter of the unit of holding. For reasons already glanced at, the progress of the large farm system cannot be so clearly traced after 1815 as before that date. Individual examples have to suffice in place of more general statements. But such examples can be adduced in plenty. Thus on the celebrated Netherby estate in Cumberland, the number of farmers was decreased by more than 50 per cent, between 1820 and 1850. "Fine farms of 300 and 400 acres, now occupied in one holding by an enterprising tenant, were then (1820) held in seven or eight separate possessions1," wrote Caird in 1852. Again, it is reported that after 1820 very many dairy-farms were transformed into arable, and this would naturally be accompanied by an increase in the number of acres in one hand8. Little allotments, too, in large numbers were thrown into larger holdings3, the labourers being deprived of their bits of land4. Where common-land was enclosed — and about 900,000 acres were enclosed by Act of Parliament between 1820 and 1850 — the formation of large farms was always the im- mediate result When Exmoor Forest was enclosed, for instance, farms of from 400 to looo acres, and even up to 2000 acres, were formed8. Agricultural authorities recommended the landlords even in the classic districts of small holdings to throw two or three farms into one, as a matter of "good policy8." The policy was so well carried out that Caird, on his tour of 1850, found many districts in 1 J. Caird, English Agriculture in 1850-1851, i88a, p. 352. 3 Carmichael, Corn Laws, Edinburgh and London, 1838, p. 13. * G. Buckland, On the Farming of Kent, m Journal X. A. S., Vol. VI (1845), p. 196. 4 Cp. The Labourers' Friend, 1835, p. 31 : — " I could point out parishes which fifty years ago contained a body of poor who, I observed at that time, and for several years after, were comfortable and happy, as to their temporal concerns : and this was chiefly owing to their occupying their crofts, and orchards, and gardens close to their cottages. The parish of Evestan, next to Potton, of which I was curate about fifty years ago... was circumstanced, as to the poor, as above stated ; but within the last twenty years the cottages have been deprived of all their accompaniments, which enabled the occupiers to keep some one, some two, and some three cows, besides pigs and poultry." 6 T. D. Acland and W. Sturge, The Farming of Somersetshire, 1851, p. 159. 8 W. F. Karkeek, On the Farming of Corn-wall, in Journal R. A. S., Vol. VI (1845), p. 402. Corn-law Period 51 which the farms had attained an area of from 1000 to 3000 acres and over1. Moreover, it was during the corn-law period that the final disappear- ance of the yeomanry took place. The greater part of this class had already vanished in the previous period, having preferred the position of a large farmer to that of a small owner. Those who had not made that really beneficial exchange burdened their estates with mortgages and attempted with the capital so raised to increase the falling profits of their small holdings. In particular, they tried, by all manner of improvements, to increase their production of corn, in order to share in the large profits promised by its high price. But when after 1815, in spite of the corn-laws, the price of wheat failed to return to its former height, these remaining yeomen were the first to suffer. Their decreased profits no longer sufficed to keep up the interest on their mortgages, and they either sold their land or were foreclosed upon3. Their estates were swallowed up by the great landlord and the large farmer, so that by 1836 a witness could state that the yeomanry "are, as a body, ceasing to exist at all3." Meantime, while the system of the large farm was thus making progress, the counter-movement, begun early in the nineteenth century on social grounds, had little practical effect. The Board of Agriculture and its most zealous supporters had initiated legislation for the purpose of assisting the labourers once more to the use of a bit of land. The agitation for allotments had proved a failure, but it had led to the passing of an Act in 1819 which empowered the overseers to buy or rent land for the purpose of letting it out again "to any poor and industrious inhabitant of the parish4." Another Act was passed in 1832, probably as a result of the agricultural riots of that and the preceding years, recommending that a certain pro- portion of all newly-enclosed land should be let out in allotments5. But neither Act produced any marked result6. The private agitation 1 Caird, op. cit. p. 89 (Hants) and p. 130 (Sussex). 2 Report on the State of Agriculture, 1833, pp. ix f., where it is said of the yeomanry that "The high prices of the last war led to speculation in the purchase, improvement and enclosure of land ; money was borrowed on the paternal estate for speculations of this nature, which, at the time, were not considered improvident. Prices have fallen, the debt still remains, or the estate has changed owners, and the interval between the fall of prices and the adjustment of charge and of expenditure to the altered value of money, has been most pernicious to this body of men." 3 Report on Agriculture, 1837 (House of Lords), qu. 5107. 4 Cited by Stubbs, op. cit. p. 41. 5 Sir G. Nicholls, History of the English Poor Law, Vol. II, p. 202. 6 The Earl of Onslow, Landlords and Allotments, 1886, p. 10. 4—2 52 Large and Small Holdings continued alongside of the official efforts. The Labourers' Friend Society was founded in the thirties, its object being to carry on, both by lectures and publications, a propaganda in favour of allotments1; or, as it claimed, to abolish the evils entailed on labourers and small farmers by the high corn-prices and the consequent enclosures and engrossing2. But energetically as the agitation was carried on8, it could not accomplish economic impossibilities. Even at the present day, when the formation of allotments is often to the economic advantage of the landowner, the ingrained conservatism of the land- lord and his larger tenants frequently prevents their introduction. Such opposition was naturally much more powerful at a time when the allotment had indeed many social gains to offer, but practically no economic advantage. Nowadays many farmers are in favour of allotments because they rightly suppose that a holding of his own will tend to keep the labourer upon the land. But in the corn-law period employers had nothing to fear from a rural exodus. The very cause of the low wages of agricultural labour was that the industrial crises and the depression of trade made it impossible for the labourers to migrate to the towns4. The rural labour-market was overflowing precisely because the movement to the towns was at a standstill8. In the thirties the farmers even regarded it as a blessing if labourers did leave the land, since, far from forcing up wages in the still swamped labour-market, such migration freed the country from beggars and vagrants, and relieved the rates'. Farmers were not at that time crying out for workers ; it was the starving labourers who begged for work at any price. Under these circumstances there was naturally 1 Proceedings of the Labourers' Friend Society ', 1832, pp. 7 f. 2 Ibid., pp. 9 f. 3 Cp. the many articles on the Allotment System published at this period ; e.g. in The Farmers' Magazine, 1836 (July to December), p. 167 b. 4 The Proceedings of the Labourers' Friend Society, loc. cit., state that the existing condition of industry precluded all hope that the superfluous agricultural labourers would be absorbed by the towns, since the industrial labour-market was already over-crowded. 5 Cp. among other authorities Wilson Fox, Agricultural Wages during the last Fifty Years, in Journal of 'the Royal Statistical Society, 1903, p. 311 : — " Does any one want to go back to the period between the ' twenties ' and the ' fifties,' when the rural population was so plentiful in many counties outside the northern ones that there was not enough employment to go round ? " 6 The steward of the Duke of Bedford stated in 1836 that the farmers had been very desirous that labourers should find work on the construction of the Birmingham railway. No rise of wages had followed : the agricultural labour-market had only been freed from a great over-supply of labour, and the poor-rates had been relieved. Report of 1836, qu. 1897 ff. and qu. 9590 ff. Corn-law Period 53 no need for an allotment system as a means of keeping labourers on the land, where they were obliged to stay whatever happened. On the other hand the farmers held that labourers' allotments were against their interests, since the labourers might prefer working on their own land to working for an employer1. The landlords, whose main interest was in the well-being of their larger tenants, found in the farmers' dislike of allotments sufficient reason for not favouring the movement. They had no economic advantage to expect if they took it up. A very impartial Parlia- mentary report of 1843 stated that land let in allotments paid the same rent per acre as land of the same quality let to a large farmer*. If so, the landlord had obviously small inducement to form allotments on economic grounds. For while they paid no higher rents than did the large farms, they cost more in buildings, repairs and administration. It was very natural that the allotment-holders should not be able to pay more per acre, or even should pay less, than the farmer. Except in the neighbourhood of towns, where there was a demand for fresh vegetables, eggs and poultry, they could not make any considerable income out of their allotments. Elsewhere, corn was the most profitable agricultural product. Enthusiasts for the allotment system, like Thornton3, did indeed maintain that spade- cultivation could make corn-growing profitable even on the smallest holding. But experience soon showed that the cottager did not succeed on such lines. If he held two or three acres, to cultivate them by the spade took up far too much time. On the other hand the area was too small to give full employment to a horse and plough : both would have to be borrowed from neighbouring larger holders4. Thus the socio-political agitation, aiming at the extension of allotments as a means of improving the miserable position of the labourer, found an unconquerable obstacle in the economic circum- 1 A land-surveyor, Mr Driver, told the Select Committee on Agriculture in 1833 (qu. 1 1,760) that " In some instances I have found that the farmers have been dissatisfied, because they found that the labourers if employed on their own grounds were more fatigued and less able to perform their labour to their employers." A land-agent, Mr Joseph Lee, told the same Committee (qu. 6099) that " We do not wish to give them so much (land) as to take away their attention from the farmers." A little book called Practical Directions for the Cultivation of Cottage Gardens, by Charles Lawrence, 1831, is also characteristic. The writer warns the labourers not to neglect their wage-earning for the sake of their own land. 8 Report on Women and Children in Agriculture, 1843, P- 15- 3 W. T. Thornton, Over-population and its Remedy, 1846, p. 346. 4 Report on Agriculture, 1833, °iu- 10,849. 54 Large and Small Holdings stances of the time. Here and there allotments were formed1. But they were only isolated experiments, or a result of the social ideals of liberally-minded landlords. How little success the movement had on the whole may be seen by an official estimate of 1868, according to which, of the seven million acres enclosed since 1760, only 2000 had passed to the labourers in the form of allotments2. The corn-laws, then, caused an artificial development of that unit of holding which the economic conditions of the previous period had favoured8. Accordingly nothing was more natural than that a radical alteration of existing agricultural conditions and a consequent far- reaching change in the customary size of holdings should be expected from the abolition of the corn-laws in 1 846. 1 Report on Agriculture, 1833, °»u> i°»249, 10,997 ff. ; also the Report on the Employment of Women and Children, 1843, p. 15 ; and the Journal R. A. S., Vol. IX, p. 127. 8 G. C. Brodrick, English Land and English Landlords, 1881, p. 234. 8 Certain political motives may also have contributed in some cases to the establishment of small holdings. When the great Anti-Corn Law agitation began about 1840, it was recognised in the Free Trade camp that the agitation must be extended to the rural constituencies. The old Chandos clause was dug up, according to which forty shilling freeholders had a right to a vote. When in 1843 Lord Morpeth, M.P. for the West Riding, failed to secure re-election, Cobden determined to put the ' ' forty-shilling freehold system " into operation. The Free Traders, with the large sums at their disposal, were not long in obtaining the 5000 votes which they required, and Lord Morpeth was duly re-elected. There is no evidence as to the exact extent to which the activity of the Anti-Corn Law League was carried in this direction. After the dissolution of the League its policy of creating freeholders naturally came to an end also. But it was continued by James Taylor, who founded a freehold land society at Birmingham in 1847. By 1853 there were five such societies in Birmingham, which had bought nineteen estates and created 2300 allotments upon them. Some weeks after Taylor's society was founded Cobden started the National Freehold Land Society, also for electoral purposes. But it seems impossible that these associations should have led to any serious development of small holdings, in view of their small number and local nature. For a fuller account see Th. Beggs, Freehold Land Societies, \njournal of the Royal Statistical Society, Vol. XVI (1853), pp. 338 ff. CHAPTER III FROM THE ABOLITION OF THE CORN-LAWS TO THE DEVELOPMENT OF FOREIGN COMPETITION (a) The Agricultural History of the First Thirty Years of Free Trade. IN 1846 the landed interest believed that the much dreaded fall in wheat-prices, which had begun after the break-up of the Con- tinental System, would now at last become a serious fact. The Free Traders too believed that the price would fall rapidly, and the only difference between their view and that of the Protec- tionists was that they regarded the prospect from an optimistic instead of a pessimistic standpoint. This coming revolution in prices was also expected to produce considerable alteration in the relative positions of the various types of agricultural holding. James Caird, the best authority on agriculture whom England has ever possessed, predicted in I85I1 that in the immediate future there would be a decrease in corn-production, but that with the increasing population and its growing wealth, together with the improved means of com- munication, pasture-farming and market-gardening would prosper. And as these branches of production, which would partly replace arable farming, required industry, care, skill and attention to so much greater a degree than corn-growing, large holdings such as existed in the eastern counties would no longer be profitably manageable by one man. Accordingly there would be a decrease in the number of large farms, and more capital and labour would be concentrated on the working of smaller areas. Thornton2, Alister3 and others wrote in 1 Caird, English Agriculture, pp. 483 f. 2 Thornton, op. cit. p. 329 : — " The repeal of the corn-laws might thus cause the race of large capitalists to disappear from the occupation of the soil, and to be replaced by small farmers, holding on an average, perhaps, not more than fifty acres each." 8 R. Alister, Barriers to the National Prosperity of Scotland, Edinburgh, 1853, p. 51 :— " High-farming must now be the order of the day ; and the inevitable consequence will be, that farms will become less in size, for it will not pay now for one man to take two farms while his capital is barely sufficient for one." 56 Large and Small Holdings the same sense. Their expectations were quite correct in theory, but in practice they remained unfulfilled. The assumption on which all such deductions were based did not prove justified. Contrary to all expectation, there was no serious fall in the price of wheat in the thirty years following the abolition of the corn-laws. Between 1847 and 1881 wheat was at about $2s. a quarter. This was not much below the average for the period 1815 to 1846, which was between 56^. and 57.$-. J In spite, however, of the small change in wheat-prices, considerable alterations in English agriculture did begin with the year 1846. But they were of a different kind from those which had been expected. The significance of the first thirty years of agricultural free trade was that corn-production, far from being abandoned, was made more profitable than ever. In the corn-law period a price of $2s. had always produced the cry of agricultural distress2. But after 1846 the same price saw agriculture flourishing, so much so that the years from 1850 to 1880 have come to be regarded as " the good old times " of arable farming. The question arises as to why it was that the same price produced such different results in the two periods. The present writer has attempted to answer this question in another place3, and must refer the reader to that earlier publication if what is here said on the subject appears to be too concise. The changes which began in 1846 were of various kinds. For one thing, the economic conceptions of the farmers themselves under- went a considerable revolution. Under the corn-laws they had reckoned on high prices and regarded relatively low prices as an exception. Now they reckoned on low prices, and it was the relatively high prices which were regarded as exceptional. The general expectation of a fall in prices consequent on the abolition of the protective duties set the corn-growers seeking some way of meeting such a fall. The obvious means was to diminish the cost of production. But as in fact prices only fell very slightly, a large profit was made out of the lowered cost thus originated. Chief among the improvements made with this end in view was drainage. Caird states that between 1848 and 1878 about ^"10,000,000 was expended for this purpose4. Artificial manures were also brought into common use, and agriculture generally was put upon a scientific basis. Among the great contributors to this result were the Royal 1 Levy, Die Not etc., pp. 109 and n8. 1 Ibid., pp. 19 f., 48 and 63. * Ibid., pp. noff. 4 Caird, The Landed Interest, 1878, pp. 81 f. After the Repeal of the Corn-laws 57 Agricultural Society, and of individuals J. B. Lawes, Pusey, Mechi and Voelker. Instead of more or less exhausting the soil, as had still been common even up to 1846, scientific analysis of its quality was now undertaken, and the principle applied of replacing as far as possible what was taken from it1. Lastly, the use of agricultural machinery was rapidly and profitably extended*. In addition to these efforts of their own, the farmers were helped in their attempt to reduce cost of production by the cheapening of transport, and especially by the great extension of the railway network. In regard of technical progress the agriculture of 1846 to 1879 stands in sharp contrast to that of the corn-law period. " The abo- lition of the Corn Laws in 1846 may be taken as the critical date in the history of the agriculture of the century," writes Professor Somerville. " Since that time its progress has been steady, and for many years its results were satisfactory*." But it is possible that not all these improvements together would have made the great change which actually was achieved in English agriculture if it had not been for another development, which may be said to have appeared as altogether a new phenomenon after 1846. Pasture-farming came to the front. Throughout the corn-law period it had been a neglected branch of agriculture; but from 1846 onwards it became an object of the greatest interest to farmers and land- owners. Its profitableness increased continually, and contributed essentially to the remarkable advance made by English agriculture in the first thirty years of free trade. This success of pasture-farming depended on the greatly increased demand for meat after the year 1846. English industry, which had not only not increased its exports, but at times had even found them diminishing between 1815 and 1846, experienced a great revival after the abolition of the duties on the necessaries of life4. The imports of foreign provisions were balanced by the export of the products of home industries. The value of British and Irish exports rose from £47,284,488 in 1842 to £189,953,957 in 1869. Further, with the increasing well-being of the working classes the effective demand of the home market increased. Wages, both on the land and in the 1 Caird, The Landed Interest, 1878, pp. 22 ff. 2 Besides the authorities cited in Levy, op. cit., see also John Noble, Fiscal Legislation, 1842-1865, 1867, pp. 158-162. 3 Wm. Somerville, Agricultural Progress in the Nineteenth Century, in The Bath and West and Southern Counties Society 's Journal, Vol. XII (1902), p. 15. * Spencer Walpole, op. cit. Vol. v, pp. 151-153. 58 Large and Small Holdings towns, rose rapidly after the introduction of free trade1. On the land, according to Caird, they rose from 9^. yd. in 1850 to 14^. in i8782. The price of bread remaining the same, or even falling somewhat3, the purchasing-power of wages in regard of all other provisions must have risen greatly so soon as the money-wage went up. The people could once again enjoy the animal food which they had so long been compelled to renounce. Hitherto bread and potatoes had been their staple diet: now they could add some amount of meat, butter and cheese. In 1851, five years after the abolition of the corn-laws, Caird reported4 that though bread was still the chief food of the great mass of the population, the consumption of meat and cheese was increasing enormously in the manufacturing districts, where wages were high. Even in the agricultural districts, he said, the labourers were beginning to eat meat occasionally, or to add a little cheese to their bread. It would seem that the increased demand for animal food in the first thirty years of free trade was mainly for fresh meat and perhaps for cheese. Butter, milk, eggs and poultry were less in demand. At any rate the increased consumption of fresh meat is the point always specially emphasized by the writers of the period5. Accordingly the price of that commodity rose considerably6; and under the comparatively undeveloped transport conditions foreign competition hardly entered into this sphere7. The rising price of meat made the hitherto neglected art of pasture-farming profitable, and farmers quickly took it up. Un- fortunately there are no reliable agricultural statistics of earlier date than 1867. But the series of figures beginning in that year shows that between 1 867 and 1 874 the cattle and sheep kept had increased by about a million heads, the area under green crops by about 100,000 acres, that under clover, sainfoin and "grasses under rotation" by 300,000 1 A. L. Bowley, Wages in the United Kingdom, 1900, p. 130; Memoranda, Statistical Tables and Charts prepared by the Board of Trade, 1903, pp. 264-9; Noble, op. cit. pp. 161-9. 2 Caird, landed Interest, p. 157. 3 Cp. the prices of bread as given in the official Report on Wholesale and Retail Prices, 1903, pp. 221, 224 and 225. 4 Caird, English Agriculture, p. 484. 5 Quarterly Journal of Agriculture, July 1857 — March 1859, pp. 554 f. : — " Butcher-meat is now much more extensively used among all classes, arising from the prosperous condition of the labourers, who, having good wages, cheap bread, and also cheap beef, immediately after the repeal of the Corn Laws, were enabled to indulge daily in a little flesh." See also Caird, Landed Interest, p. 30 : — " The leap which the consumption of meat took in consequence of the general rise of wages in all branches of trade and employment." 6 Levy, Die Not etc., p. 131. 7 Caird, Landed Interest, p. 30. After the Repeal of the Corn- laws 59 acres, and permanent pasture by two million acres1. These figures prove clearly that the expansion of pasture-farming, the beginning of which had been noted by Caird on his tour in 1851, was proceeding rapidly. But it would be a mistake to suppose that at this time pasture- farming was already playing a leading part in English agriculture. The fact was that now at last that combination of arable and pasture so strongly recommended by the theorists of earlier times had come into being. It is true that to some extent pasture-farming had become an end in itself, under the influence of the high profits obtain- able on meat. But it was also a means to an end ; a means, namely, of making corn-growing profitable or more profitable. When the corn-laws were abolished it became clear to every agriculturist that pasture must be extended if plough-land was still to be cultivated at a profit. Only by keeping more beasts could the land be provided with the necessary amount of natural manure, and a better rotation of crops, especially an increase of root-crops, be introduced. On this followed the rise in meat-prices, making pasture-farming desirable for its own sake. There was no longer any economic hindrance to the general introduction of a proper rotation ; it had become profitable to increase the live-stock kept. On light soils, or so-called turnip-lands, such rotations had long been adopted, since it was impossible to grow corn there otherwise2. The question was more difficult on the com- moner heavy clay soils. Here the wetness of the land was a hindrance to the introduction of a wider range of crops3, which could only be overcome by expensive drainage operations. While live-stock re- mained unprofitable the drainage of such lands was not undertaken, and consequently the rotation of crops was not introduced. But from the moment when pasture-farming promised large profits, drainage began, since it had become worth while to introduce the rotation even at heavy cost. Thus it was pasture-farming which led to improved methods of arable farming, a result which naturally in its turn led to an increased production of corn4. The quantity of manure available 1 Statistical Abstracts, No. iS, p. 119. 2 The light soils were accordingly held to be less profitable than the heavy clay soils until the expansion of pasture-farming, because the rotation of crops was expensive so long as live- stock brought no profit. Cp. Levy, Die Not etc., pp. 83 f. ; Brown, A Treatise etc., Vol. II, pp. 468 ff. ; and J. Russel, A Treatise on Practical and Chemical Agriculture, 1830, p. 71. 3 See e.g. R. N. Bacon, Report on the Agriculture of Norfolk, 1844, p. 33. 4 The rotation of crops as practised on light soils (see note i above) had so increased their corn-production, that, though at one time supposed to be unsuited to arable, in 1850 they could produce corn much more cheaply than the characteristic English wheat-land, that is to say the heavy clay. Caird, English Agriculture, p. 476. 60 Large and Small Holdings from the increased number of beasts kept was also a very effective means to the same end. Indeed this development of pasture-farming often had quite astonishing results on the corn-harvests on poor land1. In addition to the other methods of reducing the cost of corn- production, pasture-farming thus contributed largely to produce that profitableness of arable farming vainly expected before 1846. Instead of the predicted depression there was a period of prosperity. Corn- growing continued to play the chief part on the larger and medium- sized holdings, though pasture now held an important second place beside it. Whether the actual area under corn was diminished cannot be decided as regards the twenty years next following 1 846. But it seems improbable in view of the fact that between 1867 and 1878 there were no changes in the arable area which cannot be satisfactorily explained by the nature of the harvests in the years in question2. In all probability the arable area was even increased in the decade 1850-60, for wheat-prices reached an unusually high level in the years 1853 to 1857. In any case, even if the area remained un- changed, the total corn-production must have increased between 1850 and 1878, since the produce per acre was increased during that period3. Similarly there is no doubt that this increased productivity and the improved technique enormously increased the profits of the corn- growers. A farmer informed the Commission of 1894 that on the .£ 1 0,000 which he sank in his farm between 1861 and 1874 (partly as tenant and partly as owner) he made on an average 8^ per cent. In 1873 his profit was 10 per cent.4 Such high profits both on arable and pasture produced a veritable land-hunger. The good old times of the Continental System seemed to have returned. When a farm fell vacant, dozens of would-be tenants competed for it5. The consequence was that rents were again 1 See for a typical example A. Poggendorf, Die Landwirtschaft in England, Leipzig, 1860, p. 234. He says that the soil of a certain farm was so unproductive that in spite of its relatively low rent several successive tenants went bankrupt. A new tenant undertook the drainage of the land. After the work was completed he tried to get as heavy a green crop as possible, to be fed off by sheep. Next he sowed barley and clover, and let the clover too be eaten on the ground by the sheep. Then, sowing wheat, he obtained a crop of 25 bushels per acre. From one rotation to another the results improved, and he very soon replaced his capital together with its interest. 3 Levy, Die Not etc., p. 109. 8 Caird, Landed Interest, p. 157. 4 Report of the Royal Commission on Agriculture, 1894, qu. 18,163-18,171. 8 Report on Agriculture, 1881, qu. 35,760: — "About 12 years ago farming had been fairly good, and then there was such a rush for land that whenever land was to be let there were 20 applications for it, and a man never considered what he was going to pay for it if he could only get the chance of renting it." After the Repeal of the Corn-laws 6 1 driven up above the economic level. Between 1860 and 1880 the demand was such that "some people were foolish enough to take farms at ridiculous rents1." But of course the economic rent was raised by the growing profits of agriculture. In the first thirty years of free trade the rise was 10 per cent, according to Caird1, 25 per cent, according to Sir Robert Giffen, who based his estimate on the figures of Schedule B of the Income-Tax Returns. And there is no doubt that in many cases rents were raised not only by this percentage, but by 30 and even 50 per cent.8 Thus agriculture, and especially arable farming, experienced after 1846 such a period of prosperity as had not been anticipated even by the most optimistic Free Traders. It is not wonderful, therefore, that the expected reaction in regard of the size of holdings did not take place. On the contrary, the " engrossing of farms," as the eighteenth century had called it, reached its highest point at this time. (b) The Continued Extension of the Large Farm System. The extension of pasture-farming after 1846 was in no way opposed to the further expansion of the large farm system, nor favourable to a revival of small holdings. Corn-production, owing to the high prices and the changes wrought by the application of an improved technique, remained the most profitable branch of agriculture. The only differ- ence was that it no longer played the sole part in the farmer's mind. The rising price of meat made pasture-farming profitable too. But the extension of the latter was not made at the cost of arable, nor did it lead to consideration as to the unit of holding best suited for it. It fell into line, so to say, with the predominant system of large arable farms. All that happened was that the large farmer, instead of being almost exclusively a corn-grower, as he had been from 1760 to 1850, now combined corn-growing with stock-farming. This resulted, where arable was the main interest, from the more intensive rotation of crops generally introduced after 1846: so that between 1850 and 1880 pasture-farming came to be a necessary and lucrative supplement 1 Report of 1894, Pt. II, qu. 25,173- 3 Caird, Landed Interest, p. 157. Cp. also the description given by Noble, op. cit. pp. 153 ff. 3 Report on Agriculture, 1894, Vol. II, p. 623, qu. 18,163-18,171. According to the evidence of a farmer named Cooper rents rose between 1865 and 1883 alone by 30 per cent. See the Report of 1880, qu. 52,808 ff. ; also qu. 53,611, and the evidence of the land-agent Squarey in the Report of 1894, qu. 7202. Another land-agent, Punchard, said that between 1865 and 1880 rents had risen by 25 and even 50 per cent. Ibid., qu. 15,085 ff. 62 Large and Small Holdings to the corn-growing of the large farm. Unless this is understood it will remain a puzzle why the prosperity of pasture-farming after 1846 did not lead to a diminution in the size of holdings. The efforts of agriculturists were directed towards increasing corn-production, but they sought to base this more firmly by combining it with pasture. Pasture-farming by itself, and especially dairy-farming, made very little progress1. And clearly the new system, as it included arable, would in no way tend to the formation of small holdings. Young's law, that ploughing necessarily costs a small holder more than a large, held good for the combined arable and pasture-farm. Besides this, the extensive drainage works required by the introduc- tion of a rotation of crops on stiff clay lands could only be undertaken by capitalist large farmers, and also cost less in proportion when carried out over a large area. The large farmer again had the advantage in the matter of artificial manures, especially needed on the heavy lands, and in the use of oil-cake and other artificial foods. But more important than all these was perhaps his advantage in the use of modern agricultural machines. The application of steam-power to agriculture was making rapid progress. But it was evident that the steam-plough would only pay its way on large farms and large fields2. Halkett's steam-plough, for instance, was said to be economic- ally applicable only on areas of 500 to 1000 acres3. It was also remarked that where holdings were comparatively small, as in Worcestershire and Westmorland, the steam-plough was not as a matter of fact brought into use4. Some enthusiasts held, indeed, that small holders might use the steam-plough by means of co-operation. But this has never been effected up to the present time, and does not seem likely to be effected in the future. The case of the steam threshing-machine was much the same as that of the steam-plough ; it, too, was long in coming into use in the districts where the smaller holdings predominated5. It was on the large arable farm that the progress of agricultural science and technique was promptly applied. Accordingly, in proportion as the increasing profitableness of corn- 1 R. E. Prothero, English Agriculture in the Reign of Queen Victoria, in Journal R. A. S., 1901, p. 29. 2 Caird, Landed Interest, p. 17 : — "A steam plough... is not capable of doing its work with economy within small enclosures." 3 Quarterly Journal of Agriculture, July 1859 to March 1861, p. 131. 4 Journal R. A. S., 1867, pp. 455 f. : — "Steam cultivation does not appear to increase in favour with our farmers; one cause of this is that the holdings are small, and the cost of hiring comes too high." 8 Caird, English Agriculture, p. 78. After the Repeal of the Corn-laws 63 growing made such technical progress valuable, the chances of the large holding increased and those of the small holding fell. In addition, the prices of wool and mutton were rising1, and sheep- breeding was always best carried out on a large scale : so that even in grass districts the case for the large farm was stronger than ever before. The fact that the profitableness of the large farm did not decrease even when pasture was combined with arable is instructive for those who claim that increasing intensiveness in agriculture must invariably improve the position of the small holding as against the large. "Increased intensiveness" is a very vague term. It is undeniable that the intensiveness of agriculture, that is to say the application of capital and labour to the land, increased considerably between 1846 and 1880. But this was the period when the large farm system reached its highest level. The increased intensiveness, in fact, was such as to consist mainly in an increased application of capital. Drainage, the use of labour-saving machinery, and so forth, were matters which made great demands upon capital. The increase of intensiveness which depends on an increased application of labour is quite another thing. Intensivity of capital is the postulate of progress in corn-production. It means a quantitative increase in the applica- tion of one element of production, namely capital, to the land. But increased intensity of labour may mean a qualitative change in that other element, labour : that is to say, not merely that more labour is applied to agricultural production, but that the labour is of a different kind, i.e. is itself more intensive. For an increased intensivity of labour, therefore, the demand is not on things, but on persons. It is not sufficient that the agriculturist should expend more capital on his holding; the labour which he bestows on it must take on a new character. But this qualitative intensity of labour has never been of import- ance in arable farming : whereas intensive application of capital has always been of the highest importance to it. Now in the period 1850 to 1880 the large arable farmer was obviously in a much better position than the small to make this increased application of capital. The small corn-grower had not the capital necessary for the profit- able use of the technical and scientific improvements in agricultural methods, without which corn-growing could no longer be made to pay. This was why districts where farms were small were 1 Wholesale and Retail Prices, p. 52. 64 Large and Small Holdings considered backward in an agricultural sense1. An experiment made by Sir Francis Baring on his estate in Hampshire shows how little capacity for survival was manifested by the small farm system at this time of flourishing corn-farming2. In 1849 he created fifteen small arable holdings on this estate, letting them on terms very favourable to the tenants. But they did not prosper, and by 1879 the fifteen were reduced to eleven. The four farms which had thus fallen in were thrown into other holdings ; and the consequence of this "engrossing" was that the larger farms, by the use of oil-cake and artificial cattle-foods, produced more corn and at the same time more beef and mutton than the remaining small farms. The steam-plough made its appearance. And that these improvements gave the farmers a larger net profit was evident from the fact that they continued to prosper, whereas the small holders had not been able to maintain their position. On the other hand it had to be admitted that small holdings had the advantage over large where the question was not one of corn- growing and meat-producing, but of dairying, poultry-farming, fruit and vegetable growing, and the like. It was even claimed that these branches of agriculture were pursued almost exclusively on small holdings, and Tremenhere stated in an official report that the supply of such articles as butter, milk, eggs, etc. would practically cease if the small farms were to disappear3. But the production of these commodities played so unimportant a part in agricultural production generally that the farms devoted to them appeared to be a negligible quantity. Corn-growing and stock-feeding occupied the chief place. The development of other branches of production might seem desirable in the interests of the consumer, but they were insignificant from the producer's point of view. Small farming, which undertook these other branches and prospered by their means, seemed to be the exception to the rule, or an isolated deviation from the law that in agriculture production on the large scale alone was economically profitable. The 1 For Durham see Journal R. A. S., Vol. XVII (1856), p. 98 ; and for Berkshire, Ibid., Vol. xxi, 1860, p. 8. 2 Th. Stirton, Small Holdings, in Journal R. A. S., 1894, pp. 90-92. 8 Second Report on the Employment of Women and Children, \ 868, p. 1 44 : — ' ' There are perhaps a few advantages attending small farms which should not be entirely overlooked. More attention is bestowed on the production of butter, eggs, poultry, honey, and other useful commodities, which a large farmer usually deems beneath his notice, and which if the whole area of the country was thrown into large farms would scarcely be produced at all, or if produced would be solely for the consumption of the occupier and his family." Cp. also on the success of milk- production on allotment-holdings, Trash's article in the County Gentleman's Magazine, Vol. VI (1871), p. 17. After the Repeal of the Corn-laws 65 same Tremenhere who paid homage to the achievements of the small farmer in the sphere of the lesser agricultural products said also that in his opinion the day of small holdings was over. They might be slow to disappear, but their time was past1. Such was also the conviction of landlords at this time, and the result was that the tendency to increase the size of holdings showed itself more and more decidedly in the period between 1850 and 1880. The landlords expected advantages in every direction from this enlargement of farms. Their rents rose, cost of repairs for buildings, fences, etc., diminished, estate management was simplified, and the farms themselves became models of constant agricultural progress*. Naturally they carried on the movement vigorously — how vigorously all the relevant Parliamentary Reports of the period show3. Wherever a small farm was given up, it was added to some larger holding*. This, of course, happened most markedly in the arable districts'. But the formation of large farms made rapid progress even in counties which had hitherto been almost the preserve of the small holder, owing to the natural qualities of soil and climate which had 1 Report on the Employment etc. loc. cit. 2 See Journal R. A. S., 1863, p. 165, in a letter from Mr John Gurdon, a landowner :— " I am for progressing with the times ; I like large farms and extended fields ; they save the landlord many buildings, they give full scope to machinery, and they meet the requirements of the march of intellect." Also Report of 1881, qu. 32,142, 32,143, where Mr A. Doyle states that in his opinion "the tendency to throw farms together" has arisen "from the conviction that good farming cannot be carried on except upon farms of considerable extent." •' Large farms," he says, " are regarded as one of the necessities of progressive agriculture." See also ibid., qu. 55,687 (Mr J. Walter, M.P.) :— " At the time when the system of engrossing farms, as it was called, came in, the landlords had the idea that by consolidating farms, they would be saving money on buildings." And so qu. 4788. Also Small Holdings Report, 1889, qu. 3809. For the tendency to consolidate farms for the sake of simplifying the work of estate management, see Report of 1881, qu. 37,610. 3 Second Report on the Employment of Women and Children, 1868-9, p. 144: — "The number of small farms is rapidly diminishing.... The consolidation of farms is becoming general, as it is found by the landed proprietors to be most beneficial to their interests." See also the statement of the farmer Overmann as to Norfolk in the Report on Agriculture, 1880, qu. 51,879 ; and the Small Holdings Report, 1889, qu. 3807, 3808 : — " Do you think that the number of small holdings has decreased or increased ? — In what period ? — I said in your experience ; say in the last 30 years ? — Small holdings have decreased certainly in that time." Also Report of 1894, Vol. n, qu. 19,149 ff. : — " In your opinion between 1871 and 1 88 1 there was a considerable consolidation of farms going on? — Yes, there was; it was constantly going on." 4 Report on Agriculture, 1894, qu. 39,166. 5 Shaw Lefevre, op. cit. p. 22 : — " Throughout the chief agricultural districts, however, and especially in the arable districts, the small farms have been largely reduced in numbers during the last fifty or sixty years, and in many parts have almost ceased to exist." L. 5 66 Large and Small Holdings suited them for grass-farming, as in Cumberland and Westmorland1. Unfortunately, the movement cannot be statistically traced throughout the period. The figures only begin in 1870; that is to say they are only available for its last ten years. In the following table2 some of the figures for the year 1885 are also given, for the reason that the classification then adopted is more suitable for comparison with that of 1870 than is the classification of the intervening years. The number of holdings was : — Year J to i acre i to 5 acres 5 to 20 acres 20 to 50 acres 50 to 100 acres too to looo acres and over 1870 111,284 62,826 45,629 7I,488 1872 18,422 93,148 1875 44,872 74,029 1880 44,602 74,889 1885 21,069 103,229 109,285 61,146 44,893 75,328 This table shows a movement in three directions. In the first place, between 1870 and 1885 there is a marked increase in the very small holdings of a quarter of an acre up to five acres. In the second place, there is a considerable decrease in the holdings of 5 — 20, 20 — 50 and 50 — 100 acres. Finally there is a great increase in holdings of 100 acres and over. Disregarding the allotment-holdings and the smallest farms, these statistics therefore confirm the evidence of the official reports and the agricultural experts. The fact that the very small holdings increased does not justify any conclusion that the small farm system properly so-called was extending. Such holdings as a rule belong to men whose agricultural activities form neither their main work nor the chief source of their income. More especially at this period, when market- gardening still played so small a part, it is not to be supposed that holdings of a quarter of an acre to five acres could be anything but a by-employment for their occupiers. Moreover, these occupiers were not all interested in their land from a capitalist point of view : they held it largely from social and not from economic motives. The wealth of all classes had rapidly increased between 1846 and 1870. Therewith arose a large number of persons in the lower classes who 1 C. Webster, in Journal R. A. S., 2nd series, Vol. iv (1868), p. 8; and T. Farrall, ibid., Vol. x (1874), p. 416. 8 See the Agricultural Returns for the various years. After the Repeal of the Corn-Laws 67 wanted to use their savings to own or rent a bit of land, even if they had to pay more in interest or rent than they could recover out of the profits on its produce. In the same way the rising wages of agricultural labour enabled labourers in some cases to take allotments even at a rent which had to be partly met out of their wages. But the class more especially responsible for these tiny holdings were the numerous small shopkeepers or artisans, widows, little investors and so forth, who as their incomes rose invested in land, irrespective of the economic results to be expected. In all these ways such little holdings might increase, especially in the neighbour- hood of the towns, without showing in any way that small holdings were economically advantageous. Where purely agricultural purposes were concerned, that is to say undoubtedly from five acres upwards, the decrease begins, and only ends where the medium sized holdings end, to give place to an increase of large holdings. This was what happened, in the period 1846 to 1880, everywhere where purely economic circumstances came into consideration, that is to /say everywhere except on the outskirts of the towns and manufacturing districts. (c) The Geographical Distribution of Holdings. The tendency in the matter of the unit of agricultural holding had thus remained the same in the first thirty years of Free Trade as it had been since the middle of the eighteenth century. Chronologically, the extension of the large farm system may be described as first constituting an agrarian revolution and then continuing slowly but surely for more than sixty years. But the geographical aspect of the development also deserves some attention. The expulsion of the small holding by the large holding took place at a time when corn-growing had almost a monopoly of agricultural effort, for the reason that meat, dairy produce, poultry and the like had become less profitable, while the profits on corn were steadily increasing. This remarkable but one-sided agricultural development, however, naturally was not equally marked in all parts of the country. It took place earliest and most completely where the conditions were by nature most suited to corn-production : that is to say chiefly in the north and east of England. As early as 1796 Robertson pointed out that the dryness of the eastern counties suited them especially for corn, while in the 5—2 68 Large and Small Holdings west the moist climate gave the advantage to pasture1. Caird, writing in 1851, says the same2. Accordingly it was the north and east which profited most and earliest from the rising corn-prices. Norfolk, Suffolk, Essex, Lincolnshire and their neighbours were the counties which continually met with the approval of Arthur Young for their rapid extension of arable and application of the newest agricultural methods. The natural qualities of the different parts of the country, and their varying suitability for arable or pasture would of course affect the question of the unit of holding, since this was dependent on the agricultural use to which the land was to be put In the eastern counties climatic conditions favoured the rapid substitution of arable for pasture. Accordingly the large farm system, as most suited to arable farming, was also most rapidly developed in the east. In the west, on the contrary, the extension of the arable area met with great hindrances, in spite of the rising price of corn, since here the natural conditions were all in favour of pasture. Therefore the small farm held its own longer against the large. In this way certain units of holding became characteristic of certain geographical areas. Robertson wrote at the end of the eighteenth century that " allowing for many local and accidental exceptions, large farms... are chiefly to be met with in the eastern shires of England ; small farms... in those of the west3." The same conditions continued in the nineteenth century, as Caird's investigations proved4. Not that the west of England had not felt the movement for the enlargement of holdings very consider- ably. It will be remembered that various writers noticed that in years when corn-prices were specially high farmers did not hesitate to break up the most beautiful grass-lands, nor landlords to throw little pasture farms into large arable holdings. What is true is merely that the process of consolidation was not carried so far on the grass-lands of the west as on the arable farms of the east; more small holdings survived in the western counties, and accordingly there the average size of farms was less5. It might even be said that where the natural conditions for corn-growing were altogether absent, there the large farm never made its appearance. But such districts were few, and the cases in which small farms succeeded in maintaining their exist- ence over a whole district were few also. It happened only in distant 1 Th. Robertson, Outlines of the General Report on the Size of Farms, 1796, p. 2. 2 Caird, English Agriculture, p. 481. 8 Robertson, op. cit. p. 3 ; cp. also p. 1 7. 4 Caird, English Agriculture, pp. 481 f. 8 Caird reckons the average holding at about 430 acres in the east, and no in the west. After the Repeal of the Corn-laws 69 mountain-valleys, as on the Scottish border in Cumberland and Westmorland, where Tremenhere found some such districts, occupied by a yeoman class, as late as i860,1. The mountainous nature of the ground in this neighbourhood had prevented the introduction of arable farming, and in consequence the small holdings survived as little sheep and dairy-farms. Consideration of the geographical distribution of large and small farms therefore leads to the same conclusion as the chronological study of their history. It shows a close connection between the use to which the land was put on the one hand and the size of the holding on the other. As the large farm system was found where conditions were favourable to corn-growing, and extended itself at a time when corn-growing played the chief part in agriculture, so the small farm system was destroyed at a time when market-gardening and pasture farming (as distinct from mixed husbandry) were unprofitable, and more particularly in those parts of the country where pasture and gardening were least favoured by Nature. Such is the theory de- ducible from a historical study of the question of the unit of agricultural holding in England. It was not, however, the theory which was de- veloped by writers contemporary with the movement : and the theories which they did develop have been of sufficient importance in the general theory of political economy to demand some discussion. (d) Contemporary Views and Theories. Nothing is more common in economic history, and indeed nothing is more natural, than the deduction of general laws from certain remarkable phenomena. The contemporary student finds the doctrine that all things change a hampering one, and he ignores it. He must have laws and dogmas which will be good for all time. He overlooks the special circumstances which condition a phenomenon, and this short-sightedness enables him to draw out general principles which are not as a matter of fact contained in the phenomenon in question. So in this matter of the unit of holding. It was observed that the large farm system had continued to develop in England for more than a century, and it was concluded that the large farm was the best unit of agricultural holding. This was the theory of Arthur Young, 1 Report on the Employment of Women and Children, 1868-9, p. 143 :— "In the districts where tillage prevails they [small ' statesmen '] are singularly out of place." " The number of small farms is greater in Westmorland than in Cumberland in consequence of the great preponderance of pasture over arable land," etc. 70 Large and Small Holdings Marshall, Sinclair, Low, etc. ; and of the Germans who followed them, in particular Albrecht Thaer and Karl Marx. Arthur Young wrote whole treatises on the question with a particular end in view. The rise of the large farm system and the social evils which followed in its train had awakened the indignation of the people at large and of the representatives of the consumers' interests. The whole development was attacked as a social evil. Young felt himself called to defend it as an economic good. He was the great eighteenth century representative of the interests of the agricultural producer. Now the large farm was undoubtedly the form of holding best suited to the then flourishing business of corn-grow- ing. Young proved, and could prove, no more than that. His very method of classifying holdings, according to the number of ploughs employed1, shows that his conception was limited to arable-farming. So far as this was concerned, he was able to show by arguments which are still valid that greater profits could be made on the large farm than on the small. But he did not stop there. What he had proved as regarded arable he extended to cover agriculture in general. He even formulated an exact size of holding as absolutely best, namely 1400 acres2. Because he saw that the improved methods of arable farming had been best applied on large holdings, he fallaciously concluded that the large farm system had brought about those im- provements. He overlooked the fact that they all had reference in the first place to the production of corn, whether the particular improvement in view was the drainage of wet lands, the use of machinery, or the breaking-up of bad pasture ; that the increasing profitableness of corn-growing had first made such improvements worth while ; and that the same profitableness of corn had led to the formation of the large farms, because on such farms both the particular improvements in view and the methods appropriate to corn-growing in general could produce the best results. So that it was not the large farms which made corn-growing pay, but on the contrary the rising price of corn which made the large farm pay. Young was quite right when, comparing large and small arable holdings, he con- cluded that the former unit was the more profitable. It was more economical in the use of horses and ploughs, and it had the advan- tage in the separation of management from manual labour, in the greater education possessed by the large farmer, and in his larger capital, which enabled him to introduce the new methods at a low 1 Rural Economy, p. 12. a Ibid., p. 45 ; and so also W. Marshall, On the Landed Property of England, 1804, P- H4- After the Repeal of the Corn-laws 71 relative cost. In a word, it was the intensive application of capital which made the large farm the pattern of arable farming. So far as his arguments were directed to prove this, Young was quite correct. But he jumped from the conclusion that the large farm system was best for arable farming to the conclusion that it was absolutely best. He argued quite correctly that the small holding could never hope to compete with the large in the particular points named, depending as they did essentially on the free use of capital. But this did not prove what he adduced it to prove. For the advantages of the large farm system in relation to corn-production were no longer advantages when other branches of production, requiring quite different con- ditions, were in question. However, from 1760 onwards, these other branches were in fact a vanishing quantity in English agriculture: so that it was natural that scientific students of agrarian questions should pay little attention either to them or to the forms of holding suited to them. Young's followers neglect them almost to the same extent as he does himself. Sinclair does indeed point out that the small holding has certain advantages in the production of fruit and vege- tables, and in dairy-farming1 : and at a later time Low admits that it could survive in the neighbourhood of large towns2. But both these writers regard such cases simply as exceptions to the rule. Their argument is constantly directed to show what is absolutely the most profitable unit of agricultural holding, and as they identify agriculture with corn-growing they come to the conclusion that this unit is the large farm3. David Low goes so far as to say that the development of large farms is always a sign that agriculture is flourishing, while that of small farms shows the contrary : for as less capital is used on small farms than on large, an increase of the former must mean that less capital is flowing into agricultural channels4. Thus the increased application of capital to corn-growing on the large farms led students to the conclusion that, in view of the growing importance of bringing corn-production to a high pitch of perfection, the large farm was the sole unit of agricultural holding which was worthy of attention. This view was apparently confirmed as im- provements in the technique of arable farming on the one hand and 1 Sir John Sinclair, An Account of the Systems of Husbandry etc., Edinburgh, 1812, pp. 9 and 16 ff. 2 David Low, On Landed Property, 1844, P- 35- 3 See Sinclair on the advantages of large farms and the disadvantages of small in The Statistical Account of Scotland, Edinburgh, 1792, Vol. II, p. 319; v, 472; vm, 613; X, 247, 265; xiv, ai ; xv, 153 ; and in, 567 ; iv, 444; v, 212, 422; vi, 262, 378 ; vn, 143. Also An Account etc., pp. 43 ff. * Low, op. cit. p. 38. 72 Large and Small Holdings the rising price of corn on the other increased the demand for capital with which to purchase machinery or better tools, or to improve the soil. The evident connection between the application of science to arable farming and the formation of large holdings naturally led to the idea that the law of the unit of management was the same for agriculture (identified with corn-growing) as for industry. Improved methods meant in both cases that the smaller unit was replaced by the larger. "Why should the farming trade totally differ from all others1?" asked Sinclair in his defence of the large farm system in 1793. Eighty-five years later, when agricultural machinery was still further developed, Caird pointed out that agricultural progress illus- trated the same principles which had caused the power-loom to replace the hand-loom8. The theory is also to be found in the Socialist writers Marx and Kautzsky. It was very natural that it should arise under the historical circumstances described above. The whole history of the development seemed to show that as methods improved large farms drove out small. The point overlooked was that the whole application of these improvements had been con- ditioned by the peculiar circumstances of the market, namely by the continually increasing profits on corn. No one realised that market conditions might so change as to favour other branches of production which were less dependent on improved technique. It was therefore no wonder that the theory of the absolute superiority of the large farm ruled between 1760 and 1880. The opponents of this theory were quite as one-sided in their view as its defenders. The question of the unit of agricultural holding has always presented both an economic and a social problem ; and these two distinct aspects governed the discussion of the question between 1760 and 1880 just as they do today. One set of writers set them- selves to discover what size of holding would produce the best economic results, and having arrived at the conclusion that the large farm did so, proceeded to show by very weak arguments that it also had social advantages. Another set were primarily interested in social policy, and finding that the development of the large farm system was a social evil attempted to show that it was also an economic mistake. Marshall, in 1804, alludes to the two parties as consisting, the one of men "who have turned their attentions to agriculture," the other of persons "who live in towns3." The distinction is characteristic. 1 Statistical Account, Vol. vm, p. 613. 2 Caird, in Journal R. A. S., snd series, Vol. xiv (1878). s Marshall, Landed Property \ p. 139. After the Repeal of the Corn- laws 73 "Men who live in towns" is a euphemism for persons who do not understand agriculture, an accusation often brought against the friends of small holdings both in the period in question and even now in districts where the large farm system is successful. The ground of the accusation is obvious. The defenders of small holdings championed them apparently in face of the clearest contradiction from the economic and agricultural conditions of their time. They regarded the consolidation of holdings as an evil occasioned by the ambition, covetousness and tyranny of certain individuals, and attempted to show theoretically that small holdings were not only socially desirable, but economically profitable. They argued from the particular holdings which they saw either vanishing or still sur- viving before their eyes. As the apologists of the large farm deduced their doctrine from the case of the corn-grower, so they discussed the live-stock, the dairies, the fruit and vegetables etc. of the small farm. They showed how the small holders had the advantage in the pro- duction of these "trifles," or "small objects." Nathaniel Kent, for instance, argued on these lines1; and he fully realised the reason of their advantage. If the defenders of the large farmer pointed to his intensive application of capital, Kent showed how the small agricul- turist, working for himself, worked " more cheerfully, zealously and diligently" than the wage-labourer would ever do. In other words, it is the intensive application of labour which he praises. And intensive application of labour did in fact give the small farm the advantage in the branches of production which he had in view. Cow- keeping, market-gardening, and dairy-work did require that care which was ensured by the personal interest of the small farmer but never given by the wage-labourer. The case was proved in practice by the general neglect of these branches of production on the part of the large farmers. So far Kent had as much right on his side as his opponents had from their own point of view. But, like them, he rashly generalised his conclusions. From the fact that the small farms were superior to the large in certain points he concluded that they were absolutely superior. Like Young and Marshall, he even proceeded to lay down a certain ideal division of an estate, naturally allotting the lion's share to the small holders2. At a later date John Stuart Mill argued in a similar way3. He too belonged to the party 1 Kent, Hints, pp. 213 f. 2 Ibid., p. 217. On an estate of ^1000 a year, he would have one farm let at a rent of £160, one at £120, one at £100, two at £&o, two at £60, two at ^50, three at £40, and four at .£,30. 8 J. S. Mill, Principles of Political Economy, 6th ed., 1855, pp. 180 rT. 74 Large and Small Holdings which desired to prove that the social superiority of the small holding (or in his case the small property) was also an economic superiority, and regarded the personal interest of the small holder and his family as an advantage which quite overshadowed any gains arising from the division of labour as carried out on large farms. But he too overlooked the fact that though this intensive application of labour might be very valuable in regard of certain products it could not compensate for the intensive application of capital in the case of arable farming, which could be carried on to admiration by means of machinery and hired labour. In this way there came to be two equally one-sided doctrines as to the unit of holding, both correct in some respects, but false when generalised. Both failed to take account of the fact that the develop- ment of the large unit of management, as it proceeded in agriculture from 1760 onwards, was only the means of bringing to perfection one branch of agricultural production, namely corn-growing, and later pasture-farming so far as it was combined with arable. Both neglected the peculiarity of the existing market conditions, which gave predominance to that particular branch of agriculture which could best be conducted on the large farm. But the history of the rise of the large farm system in England is the history of the increasing profitableness of corn-growing. It was this which revolu- tionised the system of holdings, and brought about the ruin of the small farmers, the disappearance of the yeomanry and the destruction of the landholding labourers, replacing all these classes by the capi- talist large farmer on the one hand, and an agricultural proletariat on the other. All attempts to counteract this process on social grounds failed hopelessly in face of its economic force. The theories in favour of small holdings put forward by social reformers were regarded as simply expressing a ridiculous failure to understand an economic development which a century's experience established as a general law of agriculture. The superiority of the large unit of holding had become an article of faith. PART II THE ECONOMICS OF LARGE AND SMALL HOLDINGS AT THE PRESENT DAY CHAPTER IV THE ALTERATION IN MARKET CONDITIONS AND ITS EFFECT ON PRODUCTION THE agricultural development of almost all European countries has been very fundamentally affected by the cheapening and quick- ening of transport which has taken place in the last thirty years. The results to national economy might even be compared with those of Vasco da Gama's discovery of the sea-route to the East Indies. As that brought the goods of the East to the western peoples at prices formerly impossible, so the recent improvements in navigation and the extension of the railway system have brought the chief necessary of life to the doors of every nation at an ever-decreasing price. Through these new transport conditions virgin lands in the United States, Canada, India and Russia have been brought under the plough, and their products have been placed at the disposal of countries whose growing populations oblige them to have resort to imported corn. This supply has been offered at continually decreas- ing cost, so that international corn-prices have fallen steadily; and thus the importing countries need no longer be dependent on the chances of the home harvest or those of one or two neighbouring countries : the price in the world market regulates that in the home market. Where customs duties have not prevented the close knitting of the home market into the international, the price of corn, as in England, has fallen much and rapidly. Taking the period 1879 to 1902, and disregarding the fluctuations of particular years, the fall in 76 Large and Small Holdings corn-prices appears extraordinary. The prices per quarter were as follows1: — Years Wheat BarUy Oats 1877 to 1879: 49J. 37 s. nd. 245. 1900 to 1902: 27 s. 3//. 25.?. yi. i8j. 8rf. But besides the improvement in the means of transport, methods of transport have also made enormous progress. Not only can durable commodities be sent huge distances, but even animal food, whether in a natural or frozen condition, can be sent from one end of the earth to another. Consequently meat-prices have also fallen in all markets where foreign imports have been admitted. In England the poorer qualities of beef had fallen by 1894-5 to 4° P61" cent, below the prices of 1876-8, and the poorer qualities of mutton by 31 per cent.2 The better qualities had also fallen in price, though not so much; viz. by 24 and 17 per cent, respectively. Taking the year 1900 as= 100, the following table shows the movement of prices in the twenty years 1883 to 1902 for wheat, flour and meat (irrespec- tive of quality)3 : — Year Wheat Flour Beef Mutton 1883 154 161 125 120 1887 120 118 91 87 1891 137 129 101 97 1895 85 89 93 98 1899 95 99 93 94 1900 100 xoo 100 TOO 1901 99 97 94 91 1902 104 97 101 95 Thus a very marked fall in the price of all these agricultural products had taken place since 1880. From 1895 there was a slight rise both in wheat and meat-prices up to the year 1900, but nothing as compared with the fall already experienced : and the same is true of the rise of the last few years. Such a change in prices inevitably shook the existing agricultural organisation to its foundations. Corn-growing became increasingly unprofitable, especially on the poorer soils. Stock-feeding too, so far as it was directed to the production of meat of anything except the best quality, brought only diminishing returns. The whole move- ment of the past hundred years, culminating as it had done in the 1 Agricultural Statistics, 1903, p. 100. 2 Final Report of 1897, pp. 46 and 49. * Memoranda, Charts etc., p. 734. Market Conditions and Production 77 wide extension of arable farming and later in the combination of this with meat-production, received as heavy a check as can well be imagined. The immediate effect of the drop in prices was a period of agricultural distress : to which lively expression was given before the Royal Commissions appointed in 1880 and 1894 respectively. The cause of the farmer's difficulties was clear. The rents at which they held their farms no longer corresponded to the profits obtainable from corn-growing1. But it was natural that after so long a time of prosperity the demand for farms should not fall off as quickly as did the profits from them, and so that rents should not drop to the same degree as prices. Such a position, however, could only be maintained temporarily. When on many of the arable farms rents disappeared altogether2 it was only a question of how long the farmers would continue to sacrifice their capital. In a short time numbers of farms were given up, and many of them remained unlet even at the lowest rents. This was more especially the case in the corn-growing eastern counties, Essex, Norfolk, Lincoln, Suffolk, etc. The area under corn showed a correspondingly rapid decrease, particularly the area under wheat and barley. In addition, the decrease in corn-growing neces- sitated a decrease in the green-crops taken in connection with it ; turnips especially, which were an essential feature in the usual rota- tion, often could not be grown at a profit when corn had ceased to pay3. The following table illustrates the decrease in certain branches of agriculture between 1880 and 1909* : — Area (in 1000 acres}. Years 1881-85 1891-95 1896 1901 1909 Wheat 2563 1852 1609 1617 1734 Barley 1900 1767 1778 1635 '379 Beans 415 263 236 237 301 Peas 228 209 193 152 168 Turnips 1468 1388 1337 1144 1056 Flax 411-6 Hops 67 57 54 51 32 No doubt this fall in the production of crops hitherto so important 1 See the Final Report of 1897, especially the sections Farm Accounts, Rents as a Cause of Depression, Reductions Insufficient, Rents not reduced soon enough. 2 Ibid. 3 F. A. Channing, The Truth about Agricultural Degression, 1897, a reprint of his Minority Report as a member of the Commission of 1894 : — " If the estimates of the cost of the four- course system and of the returns from roots and seeds are approximately correct, to make ends meet a return from the two corn crops is demanded, which is impossible at present prices, " p. 68. 4 Agricultural Statistics, 1903, pp. 44 f., and 1909, Pt I. / 8 Large and Small Holdings might have been prevented in England as elsewhere by the erection of high tariff walls. But after the experience which England had had of protection nothing of the kind was to be expected. Faith in Free Trade was rooted deep in the hearts of the people, and recent ex- perience has shown how difficult it is to shake it. The landed interest, being in the minority, had to give way to the interests of the majority of consumers. Consequently a new agricultural order had to come into being. This could only consist in the development of those branches of production in which foreign competition was felt less or not at all, and putting them in the place of the branches which had now become unprofitable. To this end agriculturists increasingly directed their efforts after 1880. In fact, men who intended to con- tinue to devote themselves to agriculture could not well do otherwise, in view of the impossibility of State help and the consequent necessity of self-help. And the possibility of achieving success in this direction was given by the changes which had taken place in market conditions. The fall in the price of corn and of second and third quality meat ruined a great part of existing English agriculture. But it represented an inestimable advantage to the consumer. And in proportion to this advantage opportunities were created for replacing the old agricultural products, so far as they had become unprofitable, by new. As the price of bread and meat fell the purchasing power of wages rose, even where wages remained at the old level. But with the growing industrial prosperity of the country wages were rising considerably, and this not only in industrial or distributive employments. The wages of agricultural labour rose too, since labourers migrated increasingly from the land to the industrial dis- tricts, and so the supply of labour on the land constantly diminished. Nominal wages thus rising and the price of bread and meat falling, the increase in purchasing power must obviously have been large. The following table compares wages and the prices of the more important provisions from 1883 to 1902, the rates of 1900 being taken as = TOO1: — Wages (other Year than agricultural) Wages (including agricultural) Price of wheat and meat 1883 84 85 133 1887 81 82 102 1891 91 9i III 1895 88 88 92 1899 95 95 95 1900 IOO IOO IOO 1901 98 98 97 1902 96 97 101 1 Memoranda, Charts etc., pp. a 60 and 11 7. Market Conditions and Production 79 These figures show clearly that the position of the working classes, regarded as consumers of bread and meat, had greatly im- proved since 1880. What was saved on the more necessary articles of food could be expended on other commodities, whether provisions or industrial products. In the famine years of the Napoleonic wars white bread had been a luxury to the English labourer, and meat a delicacy of which he never dreamt. During the corn-law period white bread became his ordinary food, but meat remained a luxury. Under Free Trade bread and meat became his staple diet. But there remained many articles of fare which were still luxuries, and many still un- dreamt of by him. These it was which he began to consume after 1880. Chief of them were butter, new milk, fruit, poultry, eggs and vegetables. As the well-being of the people increased they came to form a regular and essential part of the labourer's diet. As Mr Graham put it1, the man who forty years earlier had contented himself with a chop now expected a chicken, and whereas then only the well- to-do had dreamt of buying strawberries, millions of pounds were now consumed in the cottages of working men. The same was true of gooseberries, raspberries, apples and plums ; and of tomatoes, cauliflowers and all other vegetables. Nor was the improvement in dietary confined to the labouring classes : it extended to those in the middle and upper ranks of society. The demand for meat of the best quality increased ; in earlier times it had been a luxury enjoyed by comparatively few rich people. Cream, too, came into much com- moner use, till today the foreign visitor will find hardly a middle- class household in which he will not be offered a jug of cream at afternoon tea, and that of a quality which he would rarely meet in Germany ! The growing demand for these particular products could only be partly met, and in some cases could not be met at all, from abroad. They offered a new field for home agricultural activity, now that the production of corn and to some extent of meat had ceased to be profitable. The first point to be aimed at was improvement in stock-farming. The object was no longer to produce meat of medium quality, but meat of first-class quality, and also butter, cheese, new milk and cream. Pasture farming, instead of being combined with corn- growing, became an end in itself. Permanent pasture increased from 1 P. Anderson Graham, The Revival of English Agriculture, 1899, p. 9. 8o Large and Small Holdings 11,000,000 acres in 1876 to 13,400,000 acres in 1902, and 13,900,000 acres in loxxp1, compensating for the decreased arable area. At the same time the number of cattle kept increased from an average of 4,075,520 between 1876 and 1880 to 4,611,937 in 1902 and 5,100,145 in 1909*. Nor do these figures by any means express the total increase in the production of meat during those years. For the average weight of the living animal was very much increased, and also the fattening was done more quickly than had been the case pre- viously; so that even if the yearly average of numbers had remained stationary, the production would really have been much greater than it had been thirty years earlier8. The number of horses kept had increased by more than 150,000 in 1909 as compared with the average of the years 1876 to 1880. The number of pigs remained more or less stationary up till the years when swine-fever raged, but showed some tendency to increase, especially when the danger of fever had been reduced. Sheep-farming did indeed experience a set-back. But, as Mr Rew has shown4, this was small in comparison with the set-back experienced in other European countries ; and in this case too it is to be remembered that great improvements in feeding were made, and partly compensated for the decreased numbers. Feeding was however far from being the only matter in which progress was made in the technique of stock-farming. Breeding in particular was greatly improved, as was indeed necessitated by the growing demand for meat of the best quality5. Whereas "in the days of prosperity," that is to say in the period of high corn-prices, farmers were said to have been " singularly ignorant or careless of the value of pedigree6" ; now the breeding of herd-book stock became a more and more flourishing art, till English cattle-breeding was as much admired as English corn-growing had been at an earlier period. Nor was it directed merely to providing first-class meat for the home market. A demand for English pedigree cattle came from the great herds abroad which were producing for the European market ; and as these countries were not suited for such breeding, the export trade to Canada, South America, the United States and elsewhere became an 1 Agricultural Statistics, 1903, loc. cit. and 1909, Pt. I. a Ibid. * R. H. Rew, Recent Changes in the number of Cattle and Sheep in Great Britain, in Journal of the Farmers' Club, 1903, pp. 45 f. * Ibid., p. 46. * A. T. Matthews, Tenant Farmers as Breeders of Pedigree Stock, in Journal of the Bath and West and Southern Counties Society, 1903, p. 10. * Ibid., p. 3. Market Conditions and Prodwtion 81 important and increasing item. It increased enormously just after the great fall in corn and meat-prices, that is to say after 1880, as the following figures will show1. They refer, however, only to the export of pedigree cattle certificated by breeding associations. Years Pedigree horses Do. cattle Do. sheep 1876-80 3606 626 2818 1881-85 6619 3048 5277 1896-1900 32,909 3335 8765 The value of the animals exported increased even more rapidly*. In 1908 the United Kingdom exported 53,094 horses, 3895 head of cattle, 5919 sheep, and 700 swine. Since England imports meat and cattle of the poorer qualities these exports can only be of pedigree or herd-book stock or at any rate beasts of some special breed. Their value was about £1,000,000*. An industry which develops such an export trade obviously can no longer be conducted, as breeding once was, by amateurs for the sake of sport or luxury. It is in fact practised by capable farmers of all classes, and not for the sake of luxury, but for profit. The prices paid for herd-book cattle show how high these profits may be. The average price of short-horns sold at shows rose from £27. \$s. lod. per head in 1898 to £36. 3-r. 4^. in I9O24. Well-known breeders obtained prices which might seem incredible to foreigners. Some received an average of £70 for their short-horn cows, and sold their bulls abroad for £500 to .£800. Pedigree Yorkshire pigs made £12 to £2$ a head5. And breeders of pedigree cattle not only got higher prices than the ordinary farmer for their first-class beasts, but for all the cattle in their herd, even the least valuable, so long as they could be used for breeding pur- poses. Accordingly an increasing number of farmers devoted themselves to this profitable branch of agriculture, with what results may be seen in Mr (now Sir) F. A. Channing's Report of 1897* and other authorities of the period7. In 1905 Mr Matthews wrote: — "The best hope for British graziers lies in improving the standard of quality, 1 H. Levy, Landwirtschaftlicher Export in England, in Conrad's* Jahrbiichern, 1903, p. 398. a Ibid. 3 Trade and Navigation Accounts, 1908, pp. 738 f. and 1 16 f. 4 Cp. The Times of Dec. 7, 1903, p. 3. 8 The figures were given by Mr Philo Mills, a farmer of Ruddington, Notts, 6 Final Report, p. 254. 7 Cp. Matthews, op. cit. p. 3. L. 6 82 Large and Small Holdings for first-rate home-fed beef is not likely to lose its present decided lead in comparative value1." A second sphere in which pasture farming was expanded and made much progress in method, was dairying. According to Mr Wrightson, "the keen interest now seen on all sides in the dairy arose after wheat ceased to be a profitable crop," and modern English butter-making may be dated from i88o2. The cheapening of fodder contributed along with the increased consuming capacity of the masses to the extension of butter and cheese-making. But butter- making, for reasons which will be considered below, suffered from foreign competition. In the production of fresh milk and cream the English farmers possessed, on the contrary, the monopoly of the home market, and as the demand was increasing with the growing prosperity of the population, they found here compensation for the loss of the butter-market so far as they experienced it*. Dairy farming, on the whole at any rate, remained profitable even when agricultural distress was at its highest4, and accordingly the crisis was least felt in the traditional dairying districts, such as Cumberland, Dorset and Devon*. But the transition to pasture farming pure and simple, whether in the form of the breeding of first-class stock for sale or for the meat market, or in the form of dairying, was not always easy to carry out. One difficulty was in the conservatism of the farmers themselves. Many of them could not accommodate themselves at all to the new conditions. They were accustomed to high arable farming, and were quite unable to make up their minds to give it up in favour of pasture. Land of poor quality was kept too long under the plough, whereas if it had been at once laid down for grass much loss would have been avoided6. But in many cases the transition to pasture farming could not be made without loss. " Break a pasture, make a man," had been the old saying. Now it was : " To make a pasture breaks a man." To turn poor corn-lands once more into pasture was 1 A. T. Matthews, Position and Prospects of Stock Farming, in Journal of the Bath and West and Southern Counties Society, 1905, p. 17. * John Wrightson, The Agricultural Lessons of the Eighties, in Journal R. A, S,t 1890, p. 279. 3 Rew, op. cit. p. 43. 4 James Long, A Handbook for Farmers and Small Holders, 1892, p. 44 : — "The dairy farm has admirably withstood the strain of competition, and dairy fanners have maintained their position as successful agriculturists better than any of the larger classes of the farmers of this country." 8 Final Report, p. 1 29. 6 Ibid., p. 260. Market Conditions and Production 83 much more difficult and costly than the reverse process had been. At best the farmer had to wait for results, and this necessity ruined many, whose capital had already been lessened by the fall in corn- prices. Often, too, they were ruined by their want of foresight and of capacity for managing a pasture farm, which is quite correctly regarded as an art in itself1. The actual laying down to grass was often done in the most careless way, so that good results could not be expected3. And if the land were unsuited, e.g. for geological reasons, for permanent pasture, the English farmer had small idea of any other methods of carrying on cattle farming. The consequence of all these personal difficulties was that the extension of either branch of pasture farming was much delayed, and that the farmers suffered heavy losses8. Where such difficulties were not present it proved possible, to the great advantage of the agriculturist, to carry out the changes in face of the most adverse external conditions. The history of the Scottish farmers who, at the invitation of some of the landlords, settled in England at this period is most instructive*. They came to the counties which as purely corn-producing districts had suffered most under the falling prices : viz., Essex, Norfolk, Kent, Hertford- shire and others in the east and south-east. They brought with them the peculiar Scottish power of accommodation to all circumstances, They also brought a preference for cows, grass and turnips, as against the prejudice of the Essex farmers in favour of corn and long fallows. They understood how to handle pasture better than did the English- men. Where permanent pasture was not suitable, they introduced convertible husbandry, using a field as pasture for some years and then ploughing it up. This proved most successful in the eastern counties5, and contributed greatly to the development of dajry farm- ing as it is now practised in Essex and other counties. From the time of the Scottish invasion the production of butter and fresh milk has increased enormously in districts which were previously in great 1 R. Hunter Pringle, Reports on Ongar, Chelmsford etc., 1894, p. 131. 8 J. P. Sheldon, The Future of English Agriculture, 1893, p. 4: — "Unfortunately, however, it is only too true that a great deal of such land has not been laid down at all — has simply been allowed to lay itself down, and it is of very little use as it is : weeds, weeds, nothing but weeds on much of it." 8 Final Report, pp. 258 f. 4 Pringle, op. cit. , should be consulted for the story of the Scottish farmers, if for nothing else. See pp. 43 ff., and passim. 5 See an article by Mr Graham in the Morning Post of April 1 1 , 1 903, on The Revival of Agriculture, under the head Dairy Farming. For the success of the Scottish farmers even in the worst time of the crisis, cp. Pringle, op. cit. pp. 43 f., 45, 60; also the Report of 1894, qu. 13,890-13,896. 6—2 84 Large and Small Holdings distress, and the farmers became comparatively well-to-do1. Surely, if slowly2, the Englishmen decided to adopt the system of the Scottish immigrants, and pasture farming made its way in a district where according to tradition it was quite impossible. But pasture farming, in these two great branches, was not the only sphere of production in which English agriculture became active as corn-prices fell. A second was offered by the growing consumption of fruit and vegetables, eggs and poultry. Unfortunately the statistics dealing with market gardening and poultry farming leave much to be desired. The Statistical Abstracts cease to mention " market gardens " after 1896. Up to that time they showed a considerable increase. " Market gardens " covered an area of 96,000 acres in 1896, as compared with 37,000 in 1878: and "nursery gardens" had increased by about 1000 acres in the same period8. Gardens and orchards together covered 165,000 acres in 1878, 225,000 acres in 1897, and 250,000 acres in 1908*. These figures are for Great Britain. The statistics provided by the Board of Agriculture particularise only the area under bush or tree fruits. This was, for England only, 78,124 acres in 1909 as against an average of 37,068 in the period 1 886-1 890*. And in fruit cultivation as in pasture farming, a mere statement of areas fails to do justice to the progress made. For as Mr W. E. Bear pointed out in an article in the Journal of the Royal Agricultural Society6, "in consequence of the introduction of improved varieties of fruit and the better culti- vation and treatment of plantations, the production per acre has become much greater than it was twenty years ago." Here again technical progress began when foreign competition began. As Mr Graham remarked, it gave a fillip to the Kentish fruit farmers and led to the improvement of their methods7. Strawberries, raspberries, and gooseberries were in great demand in the towns, and were grown in increasing quantities. The forcing of fruit also became a flourish- ing business. 1 Graham, lex;, cit., ascribes the " new prosperity of the farmers of Essex " to the adoption of dairy farming. Cp. also Primrose McConnell, Experiences of a Scotsman on the Essex Clays, \njournal R. A. S., 1891, pp. 312, 313. * For the obstinacy with which some agriculturists clung to the old traditions, cp. the Report of 1894, qu. 13,916-13,921. Levy, Die Not etc., pp. 130 f. Statistical Abstracts, 1909, pp. 290 f.~ Agricultural Statistics, 1909, Pt. I, p. 23. W. E. Bear, Flower and Fruit Farming, in Journal R. A, S., 1899, p. 31. Graham, op. cit. p. 144. Market Conditions and Production 85 As to vegetable growing there is still less statistical information, though some of the figures already quoted include vegetable gardens. Potatoes covered almost 100,000 acres more in 1909 than they had done from 1876-1 880 1. Forcing developed rapidly in this sphere also, especially in the growing of tomatoes and cucumbers under glass2. Market gardening was in fact being extended in almost all parts of the country, but especially in Kent, and next in Wor- cestershire and Cambridgeshire8. Whole districts were devoted to it. Nor were these districts only in the neighbourhood of great markets : in some of them the means of communication did not at all seem to favour the development. Thus the Isle of Axholme, in Lincolnshire, which lay almost outside the railway network, was particularly successful with potatoes and celery. Some of the dis- tricts had been even quite recently regarded as unfit for any such purpose. Essex, for example, though so close to London, had hitherto been devoted almost exclusively to corn. Now the corn- fields, or fields which had actually been left uncultivated in consequence of the falling price of corn, were turned into market gardens, and their produce brought excellent prices in the easily-reached markets of London and its suburbs4. The high rents paid for garden lands prove how profitable this branch of agriculture has become5. While corn lands now hardly ever bring over £2 an acre, and more often only 15^. to 2$s., £2 is a very low rent for land devoted to horticulture. I visited market gardens in the neighbourhood of Coventry paying as much as £$ to £10 an acre. Nor is this the maximum. Some orchards in the Vale of Evesham and its neigh- bourhood pay ;£i86: while in Hampshire, where 30,000 acres are now devoted to strawberry growing, the land is often worth £200 an acre for this purpose, whereas for arable farming it had brought in only los. to £1 per annum7. 1 Agricultural Statistics, 1909, p. 23. 8 Bear, op. cit. pp. 267-9 : — " No other industry connected with land has shown such great expansion in this country during the last thirty years, and especially the last twenty, as the cultivation of fruit and flowers under glass for market." Then follow reports as to the progress of this industry in various districts. 8 Graham, op. cit. pp. ro, 142 ff. 4 Cp. Mr Graham's Morning Post article : — " Many acres (in Essex) which formerly were derelict have now been taken up and turned into market gardens." 8 Examples of this at the worst period of the crisis are to be found in the Report of 1894, qu. 12,667 : also 554°> 5756. 6 Final Report, p. 254. 7 J. C. Newsham, Strawberry Growing in Hampshire, in Journal of the Board of Agriculture, June 1909, p. 186. 86 Large and Small Holdings As regards poultry farming, figures are unfortunately almost entirely lacking. Mr E. Brown, of the National Poultry Organization Society, however, has estimated that the number of fowls in England increased from 15-9 millions in 1885 to i8'3 millions in 1902, and that the value of the eggs annually produced is about 3^9 million pounds, while the' chickens, ducklings, geese and turkeys annually produced are worth 2'4 million pounds1. Other authorities on the subject state that poultry farming has vastly increased2 ; in some districts by as much as 100 per cent, in a few years3. It has been developed with particularly good success in Sussex, according to Mr Rew's Report to the Royal Commission of 1894*. The rising price paid for fresh eggs in the large towns is an indication of its increasing profit- ableness5. Examples of flourishing poultry businesses recently built up are given by Mr Rider Haggard in his Riiral England6. To sum up, a change in agricultural production proceeded hand in hand with the change in market conditions. The falling price of corn and of meat of the second and third qualities put an end to the mixed husbandry which had prevailed since the abolition of the corn- laws. On the other hand the market for certain hitherto neglected agricultural products improved, so as increasingly to compensate agriculturists for their losses. Falling prices meant an increased purchasing-power of wages, and in almost all classes a new demand developed for such animal products as butter, cheese, new milk, eggs and poultry; while the demand for meat of a high quality also rose considerably. This state of things gradually proved to be advan- tageous to British agriculture. Stock-breeding, dairying, horticulture and poultry farming all developed from an embryonic state to marvellous technical perfection. 1 Report on the Supply of Food and Raw Material in Time of War, 1905, Vol. Ill, pp. 289, 290, 293. 2 Graham, Revival etc., p. 10: — " Poultry keeping has extended enormously." J See an article by a recognised authority on this subject, Mr E. Brown, in Journal /?. A. S., 1900, p. 607 : — " More fowls are kept by farmers and cottagers than was ever the case before... At a village in the Craven district of Yorkshire I was told that fowls have multiplied twenty-fold... the number of fowls has increased in the ratio of two to three, and the production of marketable eggs and poultry as two to four," etc. 4 Rew, Report (to the Commission of 1894) on the Poultry rearing and fattening Industry, 1895, p. 4 and passim. 8 See Wholesale and Retail Prices, 1903, p. 297. Cp. also Poultry Notes, in Estate Book, 1907, p. 202 : — " Owing to the continued low price of grain and meal, flocks of fowls can be kept at an inclusive cost of 5-f. each a year, while the price of eggs continues steady." 6 H. Rider Haggard, Rural England, 1902, Vol. II, e.g. p. 478 (Norfolk). Cp. also the evidence of the Scottish farmer Dewar, in the Report of 1894, qu. 31,783-31,787. Market Conditions and Production 87 This technical progress corresponded to a revival of agricultural prosperity. People had long been accustomed to think of agriculture as distressed : but now all the signs pointed the other way, as was already shown in 1899 by Mr P. Anderson Graham's book, The Revival of English Agriculture, which has been frequently quoted above. Mr Graham found his views confirmed by his tour in Essex in 1903. Mr A. Wilson Fox stated in that same year that "men of large experience in the agricultural districts" had told him that farming was " getting on to a sounder basis1." Nothing more was heard about an agricultural crisis. Thus a large Gloucestershire landowner, Mr G. E. Lloyd-Baker*, assured me, in the year 1903, that in all parts of the country known to him there was a definite upward movement to be remarked in agriculture. The same tendency has most distinctly manifested itself in the last few years. An official Report of the year 1909 speaks of the " increased prosperity of agriculture during the last few years," and states that " the demand for farms is keener at the present time than it has been for many years past, and there has been a corresponding appreciation in the value of agricultural land8." One of the greatest experts on agricultural conditions, Mr R. A. Yerburgh, M.P., said a short time ago that " If the average farmer were asked what were the present prospects in England, he would probably reply ' Well, not so bad as they might be.' The proverbial pessimism of his class would not allow him to go further than that ; but in the mouth of a farmer it means that agriculture has travelled very far from the black days of depression4." A new stage of development has been reached, or rather, perhaps, there has been a return to the branches of production which had been most flourishing at an earlier period. For the first time in more than a century corn growing has lost its pre-eminence. It has now to make way for commodities which it had once swept almost out of existence. Pasture farming and small culture have gained the upper hand. 1 Wilson Fox, in Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, 1903, p. 311. 2 H. Levy, Die Lage der englischen Landwirtschaft in der Gegenwart, in Conrad's Jahrbiichern, December 1903. 3 Annual Report of Proceedings under the Small Holdings Act, 1909 (Cd. 4846), p. 5. * Warwick Advertiser, May yth, 1910. CHAPTER V THE UNIT OF HOLDING UNDER THE NEW CONDITIONS THE period of almost a hundred and twenty years of predominant corn-production had witnessed a development of agricultural holdings which closely corresponded to the peculiarities of that branch of agriculture. With the remarkable transformation of agricultural pro- duction since about 1880, the unit of holding has undergone changes no less revolutionary in character. But before these can be described, it is necessary to classify the various types of holding to be found in England at the present day. A scientific basis for such a classifi- cation is by no means easy to find. Even Arthur Young avoided the obvious error of founding it on mere area : but the distinguishing mark which he adopted, viz. the number of ploughs or horses employed, was not much less mechanical. No one, however, seems as yet to have done much better. Fortunately there appears to be no need to establish a perfect classification, such as would prove adequate for all possible purposes. The distinction adopted here will have reference only to certain marks which, though not belonging strictly to certain types of holding and to them alone, do serve adequately to characterize such types. They concern the holding first as a source of income and secondly as a field of activity for its occupier. In the first place there are many holdings distinguished from all others by the fact that the occupier neither draws his whole income from them nor gives his whole time to them. These are perhaps best classed under the well-known name of allotment holdings, though they include a good number which are larger than the allotment properly so-called. The point is that they are of such a size that they cannot1 either fully employ their occupier nor provide him and 1 The occupier of a large farm is often also neither fully employed by it nor confined to it for his income. But in his case there is the possibility of finding full employment and full subsistence on his holding, and this is what is lacking in the case of the allotment. Change in Unit 89 his family with a full subsistence. He either has another employ- ment or holds some capital and makes up his income from the interest on it. The occupiers of such holdings are mostly agricultural labourers, but also small shop-keepers or inn-keepers, industrial workers and artisans, little property-owners, and so forth. The hold- ings may be divided into two main types : viz. those which are not, and those which are, the chief support of their occupiers. Allotments properly so-called belong to the first type, though they do not exhaust it. The second type produce more for the market than do the first, on which production is as a rule mainly for the occupier's own consumption. But they must be distinguished from small holdings whose occupiers occasionally go out to work. The allot- ment holder goes out to work because he must ; small holders may occasionally go out when opportunity offers to earn an agreeable supplement to their incomes. Finally, on both types of allotment holding the whole family takes part in the work and hired labour is not employed. The allotment holdings merge into the second class, which is that of the small holding proper. Here the occupier is normally fully occupied and expects to make the full subsistence of his family, though he may on occasion do a day's work elsewhere. If he has a large family, say one or two grown-up sons and perhaps a daughter, he will need to employ hardly any outside labour, unless at special times such as hay or potato-harvest or for fruit-picking. Such employment will be purely exceptional. This was the type of hold- ing on which the little farmers and smaller yeomanry of the eighteenth century lived, and which to so great an extent vanished in the nine- teenth century. The other classes are those of the medium-sized and large farms. The characteristic of the medium-sized farm is that the occupier needs to employ wage-labour, while at the same time he himself and as a rule his family also takes part in the actual work of the farm. But a certain division between manual labour and the work of organisation is here visible, for while the occupier is partly busied in the actual work he also at times simply directs it. This division becomes clearly established on the large farm, where a number of wage-labourers on the one side are directed by the farmer on the other. The occupier is no longer in a position to take part in the work himself: his time is fully taken up with supervision and organisation. If his wife and daughters take any part at all, it is also only supervisory, as of dairy-maids or milkers, or of the feeding of 9O Large and Small Holdings the poultry, etc., supposing that dairying or poultry farming is carried on for the market on a large scale. If this classification is valid it is evident that there will be to a certain extent external marks of similarity between the holdings of each particular class. Such marks, however, are very hard to define. For instance, as regards the average area of the holdings, the allot- ment holdings will as a rule include all holdings of less than an acre. But even those of the first type, where the allotment is a mere by-employment, may often cover as much as two or three acres. The famous holding of " three acres and a cow " belongs to this type. On the other hand a holding of a similar area may belong to the second type, being the main, though not the sole, source of income and employment. This is more especially the case in market- gardening districts. The line between these enlarged allotments and the small holding proper is very hard to draw. Whether the occupier of a given area will or will not need to supplement his income by some by-employment will depend on the most various circumstances; as for example on the quality of the soil, the branch of production adopted, the number of mouths in the family, and so forth. Where fruit and vegetables are grown five acres may suffice to enable their holder to live very comfortably1. The same is sometimes the case where dairying is the object2. But as a rule a larger area is required for a self-sufficing pasture farmer, and the border between allotments and small holdings may lie as high as at 10, 20 or even 25 acres. This is the case in such grass counties as Herefordshire, Derbyshire, Cheshire etc.3 In arable districts the line must be drawn even higher. In the Isle of Axholme 50 or 60 acres was regarded as the minimum necessary for a thriving arable farmer having no by-employment. The outward appearance of a small holding may thus vary greatly, and it is evident that mere statistics tell very little as to the economic 1 Small Holdings Report, 1889, qu. 5887. 2 Mr P. Petitt's farm, Hilden Park Dairy, Tonbridge, Kent, is or was such an one. He held in 1903 five acres of pasture, and kept (of course using stall-feeding) 10 — 12 cows, doing all the work himself with the aid of his son and two daughters. 3 Stirton, op. cit. p. 93 : — " Experience has shown that a pasture holding of fifteen to twenty acres is sufficient to furnish the entire means of livelihood to one family." Also W. E. Bear, A Study of Small Holdings, p. 44 : — " Several authorities on the subject declared that a family could live comfortably... on 20 acres, without working for wages." See also Report of 1894, Vol. I, qu. 5106, 5109, 5207 ff. (Mr G. Murray on Derbyshire) : — "If he had 16 acres he would keep four cows, and he would occupy his whole time, and would not work to earn any rent outside his own occupation." See also qu. 5585 ; 4427 ; 3465 etc. Change in Unit 91 classification of holdings1. It is perhaps even harder to draw the line between small and medium holdings and between medium and large. The boundary in the first case would seem to lie as a rule at somewhere between 100 and 150 acres. Here the farmer regularly employs some hired labour, and therefore does some purely directive work, although his main business may still be with the actual manual labour, since the number of men he employs will be small. A few words must be added as to the peculiar distinction commonly drawn in England between a " working farmer " and a " gentleman farmer." It might be supposed that the gentleman farmer was identical with the occupier of the fourth class, that is of the large farm, such occupiers having no time for actual manual labour. This, however, is not the case. The small farmer is as a matter of course a working farmer : but the distinction as drawn has reference to two different types of large farmer. On two neighbouring large farms of similar area carrying on similar work, using the same methods and employing the same number of men, one occupier may be a " gentle- man farmer " and the other a " working farmer." The first rides, hunts and pursues various kinds of sport, as do also his sons, while his wife enters local society and his daughters learn music and painting. The working farmer is to be found with his sons in the field among his men, probably in his shirtsleeves, and his wife and daughters help with the milking, in the dairy or with the poultry. Pipes, cider and wooden chairs take the place of cigars, wine and drawing-room furniture. The gentleman farmer is in fact a legacy from the old days when agricultural prosperity was such as to allow farmers to live at a very high standard of comfort, and under modern conditions his day seems over. "When prices were high," writes Mr Anderson Graham2, "the gentleman farmer could afford to indulge in the comforts and luxuries to which he had been accustomed. Nowadays the margin of profit is too fine to admit of these extravagances." " There is no doubt about the fact that gentlemen farmers are in greater tribulation than they ever were before. Unless they are prepared to lose an annual sum for the privilege of living in the country and following this agreeable occupation, they are entirely out of place. When it is said that Northumberland is prosperous it 1 A great deal of material for the solution of this question of the classification of holdings according to size is to be found in the Report on Small Holdings, 1906, Minutes of Evidence (Cd. 3278). Cp. Index, pp. 530 and 531-2, and especially the heading Self- supporting Holding. 2 Graham, The Revival etc., pp. 115, 113. 92 Large and Small Holdings is with the reservation that they are excepted1." The working farmer, on the contrary, flourishes2, and especially the Scottish immigrants, who, as one of them said to the present writer, work like any day- labourer. Mr Pringle noted this fact as among the causes of the success of the Scottish farmers, and it marks them wherever they are found in England. It will now be clear that the large farm is not to be defined as one where the occupier does not take part in the manual labour. But he is occupied in the first place with the work of organisation. Moreover even his manual work is distinguishable from that done by the occupier of a medium-sized farm. The latter is to some extent simply in the position of an additional labourer on his holding. Without his work the business would not be got through at all. The large farmer, on the other hand, does indeed need to put his own hand to the work in view of the present-day requirements of more continuous activity, more careful attention to details, and more economical methods. Especially at harvest time he must be on the spot and give active assistance. But his personal share in the work is only occasional. Here and there he acts as foreman : here and there he does a job which he does not care to entrust to hired labour. Even his manual work is really of the nature of supervision. It is direction in deed as well as in word. It is supplementary to the work of the labourers, not of the same kind with it. It follows from what has already been said that it is vain to attempt to draw conclusions as to the economic character of a holding from any exterior marks, and more especially from its mere area. On the other hand it is necessary to combine some economic conception with the statistical information supplied. Making all allowance for exceptions it may therefore be useful to sum up as follows. Allotments proper, which are only a by-employment to their occupier, will as a rule cover from \ to 4 acres : allotment holdings of the larger kind from 5 to 10 acres. Small holdings may be taken as covering from 10 to 80 or 100 acres. Holdings of 100 to 250 or 300 acres will be medium-sized farms, and all above that size will be large farms. But such a classification must not be used 1 Cp. the interesting evidence of Mr Carrington Smith, himself a farmer, in the Report of 1894, qu. 8038; 8105-8117. * Pringle. op. cit. pp. 45 f. ; see also H. Levy, Die Lage der englischen Landwirtschaft in der Gegenwart, in Conrad's Jahrbuchern, 1904, pp. 734 ff. In the Small Holdings Report, 1906, the Scottish farmers are described as "an exceptionally energetic and successful race." Minutes, qu. 7225. Change in Unit 93 without the clearest perception of its inevitable weaknesses. If this is understood it may be worth while to compare the classification adopted on economic grounds, as described above, with the cor- responding statistics as given in 1895*. There were then : Percentage of Percentage Total Holdings of Area Holdings of over i and not over 5 acres 22-9 1*07 i» » 5 » » 20 „ 28-45 4'8? „ „ 20 „ „ 50 „ 16-42 8-36 „ „ 50 „ „ 100 „ 12-25 I37o „ „ 100 „ „ 300 „ 15-88 42-00 300 „ „ 500 „ 2-92 16-86 „ „ 500 „ „ 1000 „ 1-04 10-35 » ,> looo 0-14 279 100 100 The contrast between the two series of percentages is interesting. While that relating to the number of holdings decreases as the size of holding increases, that relating to the area covered moves almost in the opposite direction. Further, so far as numbers are concerned, small holdings preponderate. Holdings up to 100 acres make 8o-l2 per cent, of the whole. But as regards area it is otherwise. Medium holdings account for 42 per cent, of the whole area covered, and medium and large holdings together for 72 per cent. So that the land under cultivation was at that date still predominantly held in large and medium holdings. But if taken in connection with earlier statistics, the figures would indicate the beginning of a new develop- ment ; they belong to a period when the old tendency to the consoli- dation of holdings was not merely at an end, but was being replaced by a contrary movement. Up to 1880 the question of the proper size of holdings was regarded as settled. Landlords aimed at enlarging their farms as far as possible. The few social reformers who were in favour of small holdings failed to get a hearing in face of the economic conditions. But as corn growing ceased to pay the case was altered, and the question came up again as one for serious discussion2. The 1 For the sake of simplicity the sources of the statistics used in the following pages and in Appendix II are given here. They are as follows : — Agricultural Returns for 1885 ; Returns of Allotments and Small Holdings, 1890 ; and Returns as to the Number and Size of Agricultural Holdings in Great Britain in the year 1895. 2 Cp. e.g. R. Scott Burn, Systematic Small Farming, 1886, p. 14: — " In looking back at a period of a few years ago, it will be seen that, so far as the general public was con- 94 Large and Small Holdings f year 1880 marks the beginning of a revival of small holdings. To this revival two tendencies contributed ; first, the economic interests of individual agriculturists; secondly, a movement of social reformers. The second is of least importance, and may be dismissed in a few words. Social reformers had never ceased to take a lively interest in this matter. It had never been possible to defend the large farm system on social grounds, though Arthur Young and Sir John Sinclair had attempted to counter the attacks of its opponents. But from Dr Price up to the Labourers' Friend Society's agitation for allot- ments, and from John Stuart Mill on to the present day, the small holding has always found enthusiastic champions in view of its social advantages. With the changed conditions after 1880 came the Radical agitation in favour of such holdings, led by Mr Joseph Chamberlain and Mr Jesse Collings. A Select Committee was appointed to consider the matter in 1889, and Mr Collings expressly claimed that it should regard in the first place the social rather than the economic side of the question1. The particular aim in view, more especially among the Liberals, was to hinder the increasing migration of the rural population to the towns, a point which will be considered below. The results achieved by this social movement were, first, that certain landlords let their land in small farms expressly because such holdings were socially beneficial. Lord Tollemache and Lord Wantage were pioneers in so doing, and a little later Lord Carrington, whose Willow Tree Farm was let to a syndicate of small holders. In the second place the formation of syndicates and co-operative associations for renting land and letting it out in small holdings and allotments is to be noted. The Land Reformers of this period, too, agitated in favour of small holdings and contributed to their formation. In the third place the State took action in favour of a revival of cerned, the question of small farms occupied but a small part of their interest. It was, indeed, a topic which was but seldom heard, still less frequently discussed, in any way approaching to that in which a question is considered to which the term ' popular ' is attached." And p. 13: — "Of late, and it would be more correct to say very recently, the subject has been again revived, and its points discussed by those who, having more influence than those concerned in the old controversies, are likely to impart their views to the public in a more telling way than has yet been done." 1 Small Holdings Report, 1889, qu. 134, and 135 : — " I think the social question, as distinct from the economic one, is a question primarily worthy the consideration of this Committee and Parliament." Change in Unit 95 peasant properties, small farms and allotments, also on purely social grounds, as in the Allotments and Small Holdings Act, 1892, the forerunner of the Small Holdings Act of 1907. The earlier Act was due first and foremost to the energy of Mr Jesse Collings, then still a member of the Radical party. Since the early eighties he had moved almost every year for an enquiry into the small holdings question. In 1889 he brought in a Bill containing a detailed scheme for their revival by means of the local authorities. In the same year the Select Committee was appointed, and in 1892 his Bill, with unimportant alterations, became law. Social reformers hoped much from it : especially that, as the President of the Board of Agriculture (Mr Chaplin) pointed out, it might hinder the rural exodus1. The Radicals looked to the systematic creation of peasant properties to put an end to the land-monopoly of the great landlords. The Conservative Lord Salisbury, on the other hand, favoured the Bill, because, as he said, " I believe that a small proprietary constitutes the strongest bulwark against revolutionary change, and affords the soundest support for the Conservative feeling and institutions of the country2." Private effort, political agitation and Government action were thus all active in promoting the formation of small holdings on social grounds from 1880 onwards. But the reader will remember that such attempts were nothing new : and there is no probability that they would have produced more effect at the end of the nineteenth century than they had done in its fourth decade or at its beginning, if the position had not been altered in an essential point. The arguments of the social reformer were no longer in blank opposition to the actual economic tendencies of the day. On the contrary, by the side of his rather timid efforts there now arose a strong move- ment for the creation of small holdings on purely economic grounds. This movement it was which made the question as to the proper unit of holding once more a real question ; and to it, therefore, the main attention of the historian is due. It proceeded naturally in the first instance from the landlords, who found that, if their rents were to be kept up, they must cease to consolidate farms and on the contrary must cut up the large holdings as opportunity offered. After 1880 this tendency becomes increas- ingly evident3. The Report of the Select Committee of 1889 states 1 Parliamentary Debates, 1892, Vol. I, p. 911. 8 Speech at Exeter, on Feb. 3rd, 1892, quoted in Shaw Lefevre, op. cit. p. 85. 3 E.g. Small Holdings Report, 1889, qu. 4005, where the land-agent Mr Squarey says : — 96 Large and Small Holdings this clearly, and also points out how contrary the movement was to current traditions. "As regards small tenancies, the diminution " has been chiefly due to the practice of consolidating farms which " prevailed almost universally for a generation previous to the recent " agricultural depression. This policy was formerly enjoined on the "landowners on economical grounds. It was pointed out that the "expense of keeping buildings in repair is much greater in proportion " in small than in large farms, and that the employment of machinery " and of the best agricultural methods is facilitated by the single " management and cultivation of a large area. The contention was " that small husbandry was barbarous and antiquated like the process " of handloom weaving, and agriculture, like manufactures, should be " carried on on a large scale and under the most scientific conditions. " These views have been partly modified by recent experience, and " many landowners and agents would gladly revert to the system of "smaller farms, and they are doing so where it is practicable1." The same is true under still more recent conditions2. The statistics collected in 1895 show that the Committee of 1889 rightly interpreted the evidence before them. The following table gives the figures of that year as compared with those collected previously3. The number of holdings was : — Year land under i acre 1—5 acres 5—20 acres 20 50 acres 50 — too acres 100 — 300 acres 300—500 acres 500— 1000 acres over 1000 acres 1880 295>3i3 44,602 58,677 11,617 4095 500 1885 21,069 103,229 109,285 61,146 44,893 59,180 11,452 4131 565 1890 25,680 109,528 101,039 62,131 — — — — — 1895 — ioi,4283 108,145 62,446 46,574 60,381 11,112 3942 524 " Every landowner would be only too happy to convert his land into small holdings." So also Mr Jesse Collings, ibid, qu. 50, 51 ff. Cp. also Shaw Lefevre, op. cit. p. 30 : — " Many- landlords have had reason to regret that they were induced in preceding years to consolidate their small farms into larger holdings, and would gladly revert to times when a much greater proportion of small holdings existed." Also Channing, op. cit. p. 297 : — "There has been a tendency to divide large farms. " 1 Report from the Select Committee on Small Holdings, 1890, p. vi. 3 Report on Small Holdings, 1906, p. 4. In face of the conclusions of this Report, based on information from the most various sources, Dr Hasbach's statement (op. cit. p. 361), that landowners continue to enlarge holdings, is quite incomprehensible. s The figures are taken from the official agricultural statistics (viz. the Agricultural Returns). Those for holdings of i — 5 acres in 1895 are obtained by adding the number given in the Report for holdings " over i and not over 5 acres " to the number of holdings of one Change in Unit 97 The most striking point in these statistics is perhaps the decrease in the number of large and very large holdings between 1885 and 1895. This is the more significant as the largest holdings (500 acres and over) had still been increasing between 1880 and 1885. The holdings of 300 — 500 acres, on the other hand, show a decrease from 1880 onwards. The medium-sized holdings (100 — 300 acres) show an increase from 1880 : and the small holdings proper (50 — 100 and 20 — 50) show a steady and considerable increase throughout the period. It is noticeable, however, that holdings of I — 5 acres show a decrease in 1895 as compared with five years earlier, while the next group does not exhibit any steady development at all. In considering the more recent statistics it is evident at once that the classification has unfortunately been altered. Only four groups are distinguished. The number of holdings was1 : — not over 5 acres not over 50 acres not over 300 acres over 300 acres 1895 87,055 170,591 106,955 I5»578 1905 8l,232 166,622 109,498 I4,792 1909 80,195 l65,66l 109,768 14,642 These figures certainly show that large holdings have considerably decreased and medium holdings very considerably increased within the past fifteen years. But they also show, what is at first sight surprising, that holdings of i — 50 acres have not only failed to increase, but have actually decreased in the period in question. This statistical result might seem to point to the conclusion that the movement in favour of small holdings had experienced a set-back after 1895. But such a conclusion is not warranted by the facts. The main factor in determining the number of small holdings is no doubt the increase or decrease caused by the cutting up or throwing together of farms on grounds of agricultural economy. But another, and not inconsiderable, influence is the amount of agricultural land annually absorbed by the spread of the towns or manufacturing districts, which are continually penetrating further acre precisely, which for that year was 14,373. The alteration made in 1895 in the method of classifying these holdings of i — 5 acres would have made a comparison with the figures of former years impossible, if the supplementary figures had not been specially obtained. I am greatly indebted to Mr Henry Rew, of the Board of Agriculture, for supplying me with them. 1 Agricultural Statistics, 1909, Pt. I, pp. 70 f. 98 Large and Small Holdings and further into the country. As the agricultural holdings in the neighbourhood of the towns are mostly small, a considerable pro- portion of the total number of small holdings must be annually affected in this way : and the loss is naturally felt proportionately more severely in England, which has altogether only about 245,000 holdings of I — 50 acres, than it is, for instance, in Germany, with its 15 millions. It is true that holdings of I — 5 acres are the most liable to disappear in this way ; but holdings of 5 — 50 acres are also affected. If the detailed statistics for this particular class of holdings in 1895 and 1905 respectively are compared, it will appear that they have decreased most markedly in those counties which are not purely agricultural, but which either contain or border on large towns or industrial districts. Thus the greatest fall in the number of such holdings (5 — 50 acres) is in the West Riding of Yorkshire, while the less industrially developed East Riding loses a much smaller number. Lancashire, Staffordshire, Nottinghamshire and Northamptonshire, all manufacturing counties, also show considerable decreases, as do Middlesex and Surrey, counties which may almost be considered simply as extensions of the ever-growing metropolis. On the other hand counties which are still mainly agricultural in character, and which lie outside the great centres of industrial and city life and the chief lines of communication, show an increase and not a decrease of these holdings. This is the case in Essex, Kent, Sussex, Hants, Devon, Herefordshire, Worcestershire and Shropshire. In Wales, too, which is still, as compared with England, an agricultural country, these holdings of 5 — 50 acres have in the period in question increased from 30,969 to 3I.6261. But obviously the disappearance of small holdings in consequence of the extension of towns and industrial life has nothing to do with the question considered as one of agricultural economy. From this point of view the only matter of importance is whether the decrease of small holdings is in any degree due to their being thrown together to form large farms, or to some similar cause. What is shown by the statistics is simply the fact of decrease, without any indication as to whether this is caused by consolidation of holdings or by the spread of the towns. The decrease due to non-agricultural causes would have to be compensated before an increase over the whole country could appear in the statistics. So that from the point of view of agricultural economy it is perfectly possible for holdings of 1 Small Holdings Report, 1906, Minutes, pp. 189 f. Change in Unit 99 5 — 50 acres to be actually on the increase without any indication of the fact being found in the statistics. It is impossible here to avoid some criticism of the official agricultural statistics. All this obscurity might have been avoided by a better classification of holdings. The earlier statistics, which did adopt this more detailed classification, show that between 1885 and 1895 holdings of 20 — 50 acres increased from 61,146 1062,446, while in the same period holdings of 5 — 20 acres decreased from 109,285 to 108,145. That is to say that the decrease was precisely among those smaller holdings which are common in the neighbour- hood of the towns, and consequently are liable to be caught in their grip. Very likely the same phenomenon might have appeared if some similar distinction had been made in the period 1895 — 1905. So too the lumping together in the statistics of all holdings from 50 to 300 acres as medium-sized holdings gives quite a false im- pression. Holdings of 50 to 100 acres really belong to the class of small holdings. So far as the observation of the present writer goes, the labour of the occupier and his family still plays the chief part, as a rule, on holdings up to about 100 acres, though of course the branch of production adopted makes some difference in the matter. The latest expert evidence also shows that such holdings are as a rule to be regarded as small holdings, and that in some counties, as e.g. in Wiltshire, a holding of 80 to 100 acres is considered as a typical small holding1. In 1885 the total number of holdings of 50 — 300 acres in England was 104,073, of which only 44,843 were holdings of 50 to 100 acres. But the latter had increased by 1895 to 46,574. It is certain that the number must have risen again between 1895 and 1905, in view of the great increase in the number of holdings between 50 and 300 acres. But the extent of that rise it is impossible to determine, owing to the forcing of small and medium holdings into one class. On the whole, therefore, the statistics only give glimpses into this matter of the development of the unit of holding. As regards the smallest holdings the question is obscured because some of them are absorbed for non-agricultural purposes, while many holdings properly to be classed as small are not distinguished from those of medium size. But at any rate the decrease in the class of large holdings, and the considerable increase in that which includes small as well as medium holdings, shows clearly what is the direction of development; 1 Small Holdings Report, 1906, Minutes, qu. 3715. 7—2 ioo Large and Small Holdings so that the statistics confirm at least in some points what has been noted above as to the characteristics of the modern movement. In a relatively short time the large farm system has thus retro- graded considerably, and medium and small farms have made corresponding progress. The progress would have been more rapid but for certain causes, some of them economic and some not, to be considered below. But such as it was it appeared to many people as an altogether unprecedented phenomenon, especially to those who were not acquainted with the agricultural history of England, and supposed that the preponderance of large farms was inherited from time immemorial. To the historian the change is of course merely a reversion to the system of holdings which obtained up till the middle of the eighteenth century, and was destroyed only by the great development of arable farming. CHAPTER VI THE ECONOMIC ASPECTS OF THE REVIVAL OF SMALL FARMING IN order to trace the causes which have led to a development in the matter of agricultural holdings diametrically opposed to that which had become traditional, it is necessary to consider the profits made on the various types of holding. For so far as landlords were influenced by economic motives, it was by the question as to which unit of holding would afford them, not of course simply the highest nominal rent, but the highest net income. From the middle of the eighteenth century till about 1880 they had favoured the large farm, because it paid the highest rent per acre and at the same time demanded least expenditure on repairs and administration. But with the agricultural crisis of 1880 onwards the conditions were radically altered. The Commissions of 1880 and 1894 paid much attention to the question whether large or small farms had suffered most under the crisis. The minutes of evidence show that opinions were fairly evenly divided on the point. Many witnesses, especially those who may be ranked as champions of the small holding, alleged the higher rents per acre paid by the small farms1 to prove that they were most profitable to the landlord. Of course this did not follow. Before such a conclusion could be drawn information must be given as to the relative fertility of soil, the cost of buildings and repairs, the cost of administration and various other points. Fortunately, how- ever, other more trustworthy indications were offered of the causes which were moving landlords to favour the small farm system. The Reports, the Minutes of Evidence, the publications and press discussions on the question agree in showing that after 1880 there was increasing difficulty throughout the country in letting large farms at all. At one time no holding could be too large. Now in many 1 For some examples see Lawry, in Journal R. A. S., 1892, pp. 391 ff. IO2 Large and Small Holdings districts farms of 500 to 1000 acres could find no tenants1. On the other hand it was a common experience2 to find the demand for small and medium farms very vigorous3. Before the Commission of 1894 land agents complained of the extreme difficulty of finding tenants for the large farms4, but stated that "just as the area decreases, so is the disposition to take farms increased5." Large farmers threw their holdings on the landlords' hands and took small farms instead6. Landlords who had consolidated their farms between 1850 and 1880 found this most disconcerting, while those who had resisted the tendency rejoiced. " I am quite certain," wrote one, "if I had taken the advice of my friends thirty years ago, and concentrated my farms, I should have them all now on my hands7." "The demand for renting small holdings is something quite astonishing8," said Mr C. A. Fyflfe in 1889. In one case in Yorkshire there were no fewer than 59 applicants for a farm of 26 acres9, and this was not exceptional. If it was thus hard to let large farms and easy to let small and medium farms, there is no difficulty in accounting for the tendency to favour the latter on the part of the landlord. As the statistics show, this tendency developed slowly and in face of numerous hindrances. Many landlords left their farms long unlet, and put in bailiffs to manage them. But this system was only for temporary relief and was not as a rule maintained long. In a few years the landlord, finding that no tenants came, while other landlords had numbers of applicants for their smaller farms, began to consider and then to carry out a policy of division. What this change in the relative demand for large and small farms proves is that the profitableness of the first had decreased while that of the second was increasing. It was frequently said that the reason the large farms remained unlet was that in these days of 1 Report of 1894, qu. 31,183 : — " If a farm of anything over 500 acres is given up now, I may say that it is an impossibility to let it ; nobody will take more than 500 acres." 8 S. B. L. Druce, m Journal of the Farmer? Club, November 1903, p. 7. * Report of 1894, qu. 477 : — " For the most part, the farms that we have in hand are large farms. The smaller farms are easily let as compared with the large farms." So also qu. 763 and 871. 4 Ibid., qu. 14,874; and similar evidence in qu. 4480, 4571 ff., 8061, 13,410-1 3,4*1. 8 Ibid. , qu. 7137-7238. ' Ibid., qu. 16,808 and 16,963. 7 Quoted by C. S. Read, Large and Small Holdings, in Journal R, A. S., 1887, p. 13. The landlord in question was Sir Massey Lopes. 8 Small Holdings Report, 1889, qu. 6076. " Eyre and Kyle, op. cit. p. 27 ; and also p. 73. Economic Aspects 103 distress farmers had no longer capital enough to work them. But obviously if it had paid to work them the capital would have been forthcoming. If no one wished to invest his capital in large farming it was because better profits could be made elsewhere. Agricultural capital was withdrawn from large farming and invested in small farming. The large farms were not unlet because there were no capitalist farmers : capitalist farmers failed to appear because the profits to be made on large farms were not sufficient to attract them. The interesting question is why small farms had become more profit- able than large. The large farm began to be regarded as the ideal unit when in the middle of the eighteenth century corn-production became the great object of the farmer. Since 1880 corn-production, instead of , being the most profitable branch of agriculture, has become the least profitable. Stock-feeding, dairying and market-gardening have taken the lead. Accordingly landlords must aim at multiplying such holdings as are best suited for these purposes. What these are will best be shown by a study of the typical units of holding in relation to the branch of agriculture pursued on each. So far as corn-growing and pasture-farming are concerned this study is fairly simple, as statistical evidence is to hand. The statistics confirm what Robertson at the end of the eighteenth century and Caird in the middle of the nineteenth stated as the result of their own observations, that in the pasture districts of the west holdings were smaller than in the corn-producing eastern counties. This division of pasture and corn-land into geographical areas persists up to the present day, being chiefly due to the climatic and geological conditions1 which favour pasture in the west. The figures of 1895 divide the English counties into four geographical districts. Of every 100 acres of agricultural land the percentage of arable2 was as follows : — District I District II District HI District IV (eastern and north- (south-eastern and (west-midland and (northern and eastern counties) east-midland counties) south-western counties) north-western counties) 687 46'! 40'! 32*5 Thus arable predominated only in the east and north-east. It was nearly 50 per cent, in the south-east and east-midlands. But in both the western districts pasture predominated considerably. The 1 J. Caird, in Journal R. A.S., 1869, pp. 69 f. 2 The corresponding percentages for the area under wheat were 10*3 ; 5'7 ; 3*9 ; r8. District I Acres District II Acres District III Acres District IV Acres Whole of England Acres '97 '95 ri2 I '21 I'07 3-84 4-I5 4-63 6'74 4-87 6-30 6-94 7-81 I2T3 8-36 10-32 11-50 1372 18-89 1370 37-12 4I-35 45-46 43-86 42*00 21-60 19-18 15-67 11-45 16-86 l6'I2 12-37 874 4-56 10-35 373 3-56 2-85 1-16 2-79 100 100 100 100 100 IO4 Large and Small Holdings main principle of the geographical distribution of arable and pasture was thus maintained, even though the proportionate distribution within the various districts had passed through various changes since the end of the eighteenth century. Further, the geographical distri- bution of arable and pasture still corresponded to the geographical distribution of large and small holdings observed by Robertson and Caird. This is shown by the following table, giving the acreage under each class of holding per 100 acres of agricultural land1 : — Class of Holding I — 5 acres 5—20 „ 20—50 „ 50—100 „ 100-300 „ 300—500 „ 500—1000 „ over looo „ Reading from left to right, this table shows how the percentage of each class of holding increases or decreases as the district changes. The percentage of acres devoted to small holdings is seen to increase as we pass from east to west. This result is most marked in the case of holdings covering 20 — 50 and 50 — 100 acres, i.e. the small holdings proper. But the area under medium-sized farms also increases considerably. Large farms, on the contrary, show a decrease. In District I, for instance (eastern and north-eastern counties) 2r6o per cent, of the total agricultural area is occupied in holdings of 300 — 500 acres, against only H'45 per cent, in District IV (west and north- west) : and in the next class the percentages become i6'i2 as against 4-56. Hand in hand with the increased percentage of arable in the east goes therefore an increase of large holdings. Hand in hand with the increased percentage of pasture in the west goes an increase of small and medium holdings. Another table may serve to show the percentage of arable farms among the farms of each class in the various districts. Per 100 acres of agricultural land the percentage of arable (as opposed to permanent pasture) was as follows : — 1 For the materials on which this table is based see Appendix II below. Economic Aspects Whole of Class of Holding District I District II District /// District IV England Acres Acres Acres Acres Acres i —5 acres 47'5 25-07 25-22 1370 26-87 5—5° » 56-44 26-89 26-82 17-56 29-00 50—100 „ 66-15 41-52 38-I3 33-95 42-48 100 — 300 „ 70-23 47-69 40-42 37-55 47-92 300—500 „ 70-94 51-11 43-86 35-96 53-09 over 500 „ 70-77 51-32 50-53 30-21 55-98 The horizontal lines in this table show how in each class of holding the percentage of arable land decreases as we pass from east to west. It is therefore one more illustration of the fact that the agriculture of the east of England is much more dependent on the plough than that of the west. Reading down the lines vertically, the table shows that in all four districts the percentage of arable is least on the smallest holdings. On holdings of five acres and less, pasture pre- dominates all over England, even in the arable districts. On holdings of 5 — 50, 50 — 100 and 100 — 300 acres, arable land predominates over pasture only in District I. In each district the proportion of arable land rises almost regularly with the size of holding. The larger the holding, the more arable land ; the smaller the holding, the more pasture. The figures for the whole country show the same thing. Only holdings of over 1000 acres deviate from the rule. On them, in two districts, the proportion of arable land is less than in the class next below them ; but this, as will be seen below, is easily explained. In the eastern and north-eastern counties arable already predominates in the second class of holdings (5 — 50 acres) ; in the south-east and east-midlands not till class 5 (300 — 500 acres) is reached ; in the west- midlands and south-west not till the area is over 500 acres. In the west and north-west there is no class of holding on which arable land predominates over pasture In England, taken as a whole, it predominates only in those classes into which the large farms fall. Thus arable land is most in evidence where large farms predominate, while stock-farming, so far as it is based on pasture, is commonest where small and medium-sized farms most abound. Further, whether the district in question is predominantly plough-land or pasture, the small farms are always mainly devoted to pasture, and everywhere stock-farming based on pasture is more developed on small and medium than on large holdings. These figures are striking evidence of the fact that stock-farming is a branch of agriculture which mainly belongs to the small and medium holdings. But it must be remembered that stock-farming is not only carried out on pasture lands. Where stall-feeding is io6 Large and Small Holdings extensively used, a stock-farm may yet have more arable land than pasture, the arable being chiefly devoted to crops used as fodder. There are, however, figures which prove yet further that not only pasture-farming, but stock-feeding generally, at least so far as cattle and pigs are concerned, belongs to the domain of the small farmer. The number of animals kept per 100 acres on the various types of farm is given in the following table1 : — Class of Holding Cattle Pigs Sheep i — 5 acres 29*9 49-8 29*9 5—20 „ 31-4 22-1 31-6 20—50 „ 27-1 12-5 44-3 50—100 „ 23-1 9-1 50-9 100—300 „ 18-5 67 62-9 300—500 „ 147 5-1 84-8 500 — 1000 „ IT2 4"2 I03'2 over looo „ 8*2 2-9 107-8 Here it appears that the relative number of cattle and pigs kept regularly decreases as the size of holding increases, but the sheep increase. The latter result seems to indicate the reason for the increase of pasture land on farms of over 1000 acres as compared with those of 500 — 1000 acres. It is not that ordinary stock-farming increases, but that these very large holdings often consist of great sheep-walks ; that is to say, wide stretches of land covered with poor pasture. It is not so easy to show the extent to which the other branches of agriculture, as fruit and vegetable growing and poultry-farming, are developed on the various classes of holding. No statistics are available. But almost all reports and publications on the subject mention these businesses as being primarily conducted on the small farms2. It appears that where the soil is suited neither for pasture nor market-gardening, small farms are often conspicuous by their absence3. " A rapid development of special crops, such as celery, carrots, beetroot and other vegetables" is ascribed in the first place to small holders, as for example those in the Isle of Axholme, who have chiefly developed the cultivation of potatoes, celery and cabbage4. So with poultry-farming. The large farmers left it alone, as they did dairy-farming and stock-breeding6. On hundreds of 1 Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, 1886, p. 104. 3 Small Holdings Report, 1889, qu. 7389; and 3/65, 3766, 3773- Cp. also H. Samuel, Liberalism, 1902, Chapter V, The Land Question. 3 Final Report, p. 357: — "In counties like Suffolk, where there is little good pasture land or land suited for market-gardening, small farms and freehold farmers are rare." 4 Ibid., p. 355. Cp. also Bear, A Study etc., p. 18. 5 Lord Wantage, in Small Holdings Report, 1889, qu. 1945. Economic Aspects 107 large farms fowls, eggs, vegetables, fruit, honey, etc. are only produced for home consumption, whereas it would be hard to find a small farmer who does not send considerable quantities of these products to market1. Accordingly, districts specially suited for fruit or vegetables are usually covered with small holdings, as in the famous Vale of Evesham, one of the best fruit districts in England, and also one exclusively occupied by small holders* : and in a strawberry-growing district in the neighbourhood of Southampton, where the largest fruit gardens are not more than 35 acres, and the ordinary size is from \ to 10 acres3. " In the Chatteris neighbourhood of Cambridgeshire, numbers of small holders have been able to pay rents of over £2 an acre... and have made a good thing out of holdings of four to fifty acres, growing potatoes and early carrots, besides other produce," wrote Mr Channing in his summary of the evidence before the 1894 Com- mission4. All these branches of production belong to the small holder. Corn-growing, on the contrary, and particularly corn-growing for the market, is a point in which they are very weak. The corn-production of the small holdings is almost entirely for home consumption, whether for bread for the family, or, what is much more common in modern times, for the purpose of providing fodder and straw. Allotment holders of 4 — 5 acres and upwards, even if they have any arable, sell no corn, but feed it all to their pigs and cattle, their horse if they keep one, and their fowls. But even on small holdings of a larger size corn-growing plays a very small part, as the statistics quoted have shown. Even in those rare cases where such a holding is mainly arable, as in the often-quoted Isle of Axholme (celebrated even in Arthur Young's time), this holds good6. A local expert6 informed the present writer that a holding of 60 acres would as a rule be divided as follows : — 8 acres under permanent pasture, IO under potatoes, 4 under turnips, 3 under mangold, 5 under clover, and the remaining 30 acres under wheat, oats and barley. The occu- pier's main source of income would be his potato crop, together with the three or four cows and ten or twelve pigs he would keep, and any other live-stock. His oats, barley, turnips, clover and mangolds would be fed to his beasts. The product of the 8£ acres of wheat would be 1 H. Rew, Report on North Devon, 1895 (C. 7728), p. 15 : — " It is the regular practice for the wives and daughters of the small farmers. ..to take poultry, eggs, butter and clotted cream, as well as garden produce, honey etc., into the market once a week and there sell it direct to the customers." Cp. also Eyre, op. cit. pp. 10 f. 8 W. E. Bear, in Journal R. A. S., 1899, pp. 36, 40. 8 Ibid., p. 47. 4 Final Report, p. 358. s Levy, Der Untergang etc,, p. 160 ; Bear, op. cit. pp. 14-14. 8 Mr John Ross, of Belton, Lincolnshire. io8 Large and Small Holdings sold. So that of 52 acres of arable only 8| would serve to grow corn for the market, and the other 43^ would be for stock-feeding and potato growing. The small farms of the eighteenth century, previous to the agrarian revolution, had produced little corn for the market, and the revived small farms of the nineteenth century follow in their steps. " Cows, pigs, poultry and vegetables are the four chief sources of profit that would come off a (small) farm, to enable a tenant to do well ; and I should say that nearly all small farmers would carry out the same system," said a witness before the 1880 Commission1. A priori, the natural result must have been that small farms, pursuing the now most profitable branches of agriculture, would prosper much more than the large farms, which were to a great extent dependent on the increasingly unprofitable production of corn. It remains to consider whether this a priori deduction is justified by the facts : whether, as a result of the different branches of production pursued on large and small farms respectively, the latter actually prospered better than the former in the period of the crisis. Unfortunately the question has never been put precisely in this form. The Royal Commissions of 1880-1 and 1894-7 considered the position of large and small holdings in general, without special atten- tion to the branch of production pursued, and arrived at the somewhat vague conclusion that the small farms had, not everywhere, but in particular districts under special conditions, proved better capable of standing against the crisis than the large. But examples were adduced to show that in some cases the small farmers had suffered even more acutely than the large, and it was therefore concluded that the small farm system was not universally superior to the large farm system. The Reports, therefore, cannot be used in this matter without first being subjected to a critical analysis. It is not sufficient simply to state that in such and such a district small farms did better, and in such another worse. The interesting question is why this was so, and it cannot as a rule be answered by mere statistics. The varying profitableness of the different branches of agriculture makes it antecedently probable that the class of holdings which suffered least would be that on which the more profitable branches were pursued. \ In other words, the small farms, which were mainly devoted to stock- \ feeding and market-gardening, would as a rule have the advantage | over the mainly corn-growing large farms. The exceptions, that is to say the cases in which small farms suffered severely, prove the rule. 1 Report on Agricultural Depression, 1881, qu. 62,310 (Mr Baghot de la Bere) ; also qu. 62,615. Economic Aspects 109 For, generally speaking, those exceptions are small farms on which stock-feeding and market-gardening were not the main objects. They were those which were chiefly concerned with corn-growing. To cite the Isle of Axholme once more. At the present time, as shown above, the small holdings of this district are not indeed pasture farms, but their arable land is not used chiefly to grow corn for the market, but to produce food for cattle on the one hand and vegetables for the market on the other. This, however, is a new state of affairs1. Formerly the district was renowned for its corn-producing yeomanry. After 1880 this class fell into great distress, and were quoted as an example of the failure of small holdings to meet the crisis8. Their history is perhaps almost unique in English agricultural history, but it is very instructive where the question of the unit of holding is under consideration. Up to 1880 the Isle of Axholme was possibly the one district in which the old yeomanry still predominated. In the period between 1760 and 1815 they had not decided to transform themselves into large farmers, but had retained the old communal spirit3, had as a body undertaken improvements4, and had successfully carried on corn-production throughout the period of high prices. But the custom of leaving the land to the eldest son led, during the good years (1850 to 1880), to the practice of burdening it with mortgages, inasmuch as the price of land had increased considerably. When the drop in prices came, and profits fell, "the rent now due in the shape of interest," sums up Mr Pringle in his report to the Commissioners of 1894, "far exceeds what would be a 'fair rent5.'" This was the ruin of the old corn-growing yeomanry, who perhaps felt the crisis more immediately than the farmers, since the latter could get their rents lowered. They disappeared ; and their successors, together with a few wise survivors of their own class, diminished the corn crops in favour of other, now more profitable, agricultural pursuits, and especially developed stock-feeding and potato and celery growing. This policy proved a complete success8. Agricultural distress practically 1 Channing, op. cit. p. 284. He says that the area under wheat fell off considerably, while that under oats (probably for use as fodder) increased by 40 %, while " there has been a rapid and persistent development of special crops, such as celery, carrots, beetroot, and other vegetables." O. Stillich, Die englische Agrarkrisis, Jena, 1899, p. 92. Bear, A Study etc., pp. 16, 24. Drainage, in particular, was carried out at their common expense. On this point cp. also Rae, op. cit. p. 563. Report on the Isle of Axholme, by R. Hunter Pringle, 1894, Vol. XVI, It. I, p. 682. Bear, A Study etc., p. 24 : — " Small farming in the Isle of Axholme must be regarded as a success." no Large and Small Holdings disappeared from the Isle, and altogether from the small farms and allotments devoted to vegetable-growing1. Small farming, therefore, in the Isle of Axholme proved entirely successful so far as it was concerned with live-stock and vegetable-growing, but failed as badly as large farming, or perhaps more so, in regard of corn-production. The same was true of other districts. Where small farmers de- pended on their corn-crops they suffered severely from the crisis. Cases of this kind were naturally most common in the eastern counties. Thus the small farmers of Bedfordshire were reported to be doing very badly; and their holdings were chiefly arable2. So, too, a gloomy picture was painted of the condition of Norfolk farmers holding from 50 to 100 acres3; and again the class con- cerned seems to have been mainly occupied in corn-growing. For Norfolk was preponderantly an arable county, even the smallest hold- ings, of i to 5 and 5 to 20 acres, being under the plough4. The case was the same in Suffolk, where pasture and vegetable-growing were very slow to develop8. In fact, wherever distress among the smaller land- holders is reported it turns out that specifically arable districts are concerned-: and in such districts the small holders undoubtedly suffered more than the large6. Where stock-feeding and market-gardening or the like were the chief business, matters were quite otherwise. It is a recognised fact, and appears on the face of the Report of the Commission of 1894, that agricultural distress was much less in the pasture districts than in the arable districts. Now the statistics quoted above show that it was in the pasture districts of the west and north-west that most of the small and medium-sized holdings of the country were situated, while large farms were much less common there than in the eastern counties. Therefore it is clear at once that so far as stock-farming, and especially pasture-farming, is concerned, the depression was much less felt on small farms than on large. This general proposition may be supple- mented by various individual examples. Thus small farmers in Devonshire, who only grew so much corn as would enable them to buy their seed again out of the profits, are reported to have suffered 1 Rider Haggard, op. cit. Vol. n, p. 196: — " In the district (Epworth) there was nothing that approached to distress." 2 Report of 1894, qu. 35,652. * Report of 1881, qu. 51,874 ff. ; 52,132 ff. ; and 51, 935 f. 4 See the tables in Appendix II below. 5 Channing, op. cit. pp. 7, 289. 8 Bear, in Journal R. A. S., 1891, pp. 269 ff. Such districts were North Yorkshire, Durham, Lincolnshire, East Suffolk and Norfolk. Economic Aspects 1 1 1 very little from the crisis1. In Huntingdonshire "the small grass- farmers, who depend on milk and not on corn-growing," were reported to have been "able to hold their own considerably better than those who have had anything to do with trying to grow corn*." Where the small holders sold milk and vegetables and "owing to the nature of their husbandry are not corn -growing," no signs of depression were to be found3. A witness informed the Committee of 1906 that "In certain districts of Cheshire and Flintshire there are small holdings which are all permanent pasture, where the production is cheese-making ; these are almost invariably doing well4." The demand for small holdings, too, proved greater where they included little plough-land'. As an expert put it : — " I observe that a small farmer who keeps clear of the plough generally does well ; but whenever arable land is touched, his life appears to me to be one of toil and penury8." For instance, on the great Stratton estate the most successful and most coveted small farms were those which were on grass lands7. That well-known agricultural writer Mr T. E. Kebbel said in the 1893 edition of his book on The Agricultural Labourer that " no argument is wanted at this time of day to show that a man can thrive on a small grass farm, who would starve on a small corn farm8." The same was true in an enhanced degree of allotment-holdings. Their success, too, depended on their being devoted to live-stock and pasture. When Lord Wenlock offered to form arable allotments on his Yorkshire property, not a single application was made for them, and it appeared that such holdings were intensely unpopular9. In other districts there was so great a demand for grass allotments that there were numerous competitors for every one available, and their rents hardly fell at all even in the worst times10. It remains to compare the position of the small holdings with that of the larger farms. Where the former grew little wheat as compared with the latter, they proved to be much more 1 Read, op. cit. p. 12. 2 Report of 1894, qu. 41,206 ; and Bear, A Study etc., p. 36. 8 Report of 1881, qu. 62,307 ; and so qu. 47,904. * Small Holdings Report, 1906, Minutes, qu. 6739 ; cp. also Mr Bear's instructive article Prospects for Small Holdings, in The Bath and West and Southern Counties Journal, 1908, P- 39- 8 Report of 1894, qu. 3546 (Mr Ingram): — "There is not nearly the same difficulty in letting a farm, anything up to about 100 acres (as in letting the larger ones), assuming there is not too much arable land in it." 8 See Read, op. cit. p. 23. 7 Stirton, op. cit. p. 93. 8 T. E. Kebbel, The Agricultural Labourer, ed. 1893, p. 160. 9 Earl of Onslow, op. cit. p. 41. 10 Ibid., p. 47. 1 i 2 Large and Small Holdings successful1. Cheshire, which had long been celebrated for its small and medium-sized dairy-farms, was said to have suffered less from the depression than any other county in England2. Wherever stock- feeding and dairy-farming flourished small holdings prospered, while large farms did not do nearly so well3. Monmouthshire4, Leicester- shire8, and other counties might be cited6. The same was true where the small holders devoted themselves to fruit, vegetables, or poultry- breeding. To fruit-farming, for instance, was attributed the superior prosperity of the small holders and cottagers as compared with the large farmers in Herefordshire. The latter gave no such intensive care to the fruit as the former7. In East Sussex, where rents had as a rule been very remarkably reduced, the small poultry-farms were in many cases found to be paying as much as ever8. In many parts of the country the small holders, selling no corn, had even profited con- siderably by the fall in its price, since they got cheaper food for their cattle, pigs and fowls9. Speaking generally, therefore, the success of the small and medium holdings in withstanding the crisis depended on the branch of agricul- ture which they pursued. Even in the great days of corn-growing the small farm had proved its economic inferiority to the large farm so far as this commodity was concerned. When corn-growing fell on evil times, the small arable farmers suffered even more severely than the large. But comparatively few small holdings had been given up to corn : and the branches of production to which they were mostly devoted and in which they excelled were precisely those which after 1880 became most profitable. Therefore in general the small holdings had a better chance than the large during the period of depression. Accordingly the evidence as to distress among small holders, if rightly interpreted, is seen to concern exceptions to the general rule ; only an 1 Cp. A. J. Burrows, The Agricultural Depression, 1882, pp. n f. : — "At this moment very few small farms remain upon the hands of the landowners, and many of these have lately been let at an increased rental ; while many large arable farms are unlettable even at con- siderably reduced rents." 2 Report of 1894, qu. 10,407. 3 Ibid., qu. 4218-4220, evidence of Sir Gardner Engleheart : — " Looking generally at the property under your management, would you say that the depression is more felt by the large farms or the small ones ? — I think mostly by the large ones. — Is that specially in the case of the grass districts ? — Yes. — You think small farms have answered better ? — Yes, I think so." 4 Ibid., qu. 35,126. B Ibid., qu. 13,313. 8 Ibid., qu. 13,668. 7 Ibid., qu. 5541 (Rankin). 8 Ibid., qu. 3533 ff. and 3828 ff. 9 Ibid., qu. 37,454 (Olver) : — "In the west of Cornwall they (the small farmers) are practically dependent on the dairy, the making of pork and so on ; they buy a great deal of their grain, and are gainers by the low price of corn." Economic Aspects \ \ 3 uncritical reading of the facts could lead to any other conclusion. The great majority of the allotment holders and small and medium farmers, not being primarily interested in corn-production, suffered much less than the large and very large farmers. When this is understood it becomes possible to state the economic causes of the tendency to cease enlarging farms and to revive the system of small holdings. Landowners were forced to recognise that from about 1880, with the change in market conditions, the question of the unit of holding had entered on a new phase. Small farms, if devoted to the now profitable branches of agriculture (as they were in most cases), offered higher returns than large farms. The demand for them was stronger than that for large farms. Less was heard of distress among the small farmers than among their larger competitors. Their rents as a rule dropped less. All this is surely an adequate explanation of the tendency in question. It is true that it was only a tendency, and certain counteracting forces remain to be considered. But at least it is clear that under these conditions landlords, so far as they were moved by economic considerations, considered themselves fortunate if their property mainly consisted of small farms, and attempted no further consolidation or "engrossing." The economic motive for division was provided by the fact that under modern conditions the small holdings system had become economically desirable. CHAPTER VII SOCIAL AND POLITICAL ASPECTS OF THE PROBLEM (a) Small Holdings as a Remedy for the Rural Exodus. THE social and political aspects of the problem of the unit of agricultural holding have never been more prominent than in recent times. Alongside of the economic tendency making for the division of large farms into small, two non-economic forces of almost equal strength have been at work, one furthering and the other counteracting that tendency. The first has already been glanced at ; it remains to show its origin and its result. Social politicians of the eighteenth century, in opposition to the agricultural interest, attacked the large farm system on the ground that it depopulated the land ; and in recent times Liberal reformers have enthusiastically taken up the small holdings movement, as seeing in it the one means of preventing the increasing rural exodus1. Agricultural history justifies this view. It shows that a rural exodus began precisely at the time when the evolution of the large farm system began. The degradation of small farmers into day-labourers, the expropriation of agricultural workers from the soil, the enclosure of the commons, and the disappearance of the yeomanry, all resulted from the economic pressure which developed large holdings, and all at least contributed to drive the labourer from the land. The proletarianised farmer or cottager had no longer any tie to bind him to the soil, and under the bad conditions of rural life he turned his eyes to the towns as his only hope. The yeoman, when converted into a large farmer, no longer needed the help of all the members of his family; he only directed the work of his farm, which was carried out by wage-labourers. His sons, therefore, must either themselves become farmers, or else go to the towns to become merchants or factory owners. The development of the large farm system thus went 1 Samuel, op. cit. pp. loof. Social and Political Aspects 1 1 5 hand in hand with that sharper definition of class distinctions at which the social reformers of the eighteenth century were so much concerned. Further, the rural exodus resulted largely from the swamping of the agricultural labour-market, and this from the large farm system, which did not develop a sufficient demand for labour to employ all the newly-created proletariat. This over-supply of labour reached its culminating point under the corn-laws, which diminished the indus- trial demand for labour and as it were slammed the gates of the towns in the labourer's face. He was now obliged to stay on the land whether he liked it or not Young's theory was proved false; the large farm system could not even approximately employ, under any- thing like decent conditions, the crowds of labourers it created. Free trade at last brought salvation, by giving a new impetus to industry and so opening up again the way from the land to the town. Labourers streamed in crowds into industrial employments, and the agricultural labour-market was at last disburdened. Wages and the whole standard of life went up for those labourers who remained on the land1. The effect of the large farm system had thus been to create an over-supply of labour, larger and increasing more rapidly than the agricultural demand could suffice to take up. Only two results were possible. The population might, for whatever reasons, remain on the land, and if so, wages must fall. This actually happened in the corn-law period. Or on the other hand migration might increase, as was the case after 1846. Accordingly the rural exodus has been to a very great extent a consequence of the large farm system. Trade and industry developed a growing demand for labour, and the rural population, bound by no ties to the soil, went where the best chances were offered it. The large farm system did not of course create the rural exodus, but it essentially strengthened the tendency. The number of agricultural labourers (shepherds included) fell from 1,253,786 in 1851 to 621,168 in 1901, or by more than 50 per cent. This decrease has been explained by the development of pasture-farming and the use of agricultural machinery, which, it is said, between them rendered many labourers superfluous and so caused the depopulation of the land. They had of course their share in the movement, especially in certain districts. But they cannot be said to have caused it, for both arable and dairy-farming districts were left crying out for labour. The demand had not indeed 1 See the detailed description in Wilson Fox, Agricultural Wages, in Journal R. Statistical Soc,, 1903. Also H. Levy, Landarbeiterfrage und Landfittcht in England, in Brauns Archiv, 1903, pp. 497 ff. 8— a n6 Large and Small Holdings increased absolutely : but nevertheless the supply was diminished to such an extent that labourers often simply could not be found, more especially, as Mr Rider Haggard has shown1, when younger men were wanted. If it was the extension of pasture or the introduction of machinery which was driving the people off the land, they might have gone to the districts where agricultural labour was in such great demand, instead of to London, Birmingham or Manchester. To explain why they did not do so would need a description at large of the differences between the life of the labourer on the land and in the towns2. The labourer left the land because the towns offered him higher wages, more enjoyment, more physical and mental excitement, greater freedom and a higher social position. He was not concerned with the fact that the farmer had to pay higher wages and generally to provide better conditions of life than had formerly been the case. His comparison was not between past and present, but between two present-day standards; and he preferred that of the town. The large farm system had thus failed to fulfil the social hopes which it had held out. It was to have provided the labourers with steady work at high wages, and so to keep them on the land. As a fact, its tendency was to develop a greater supply of labour than it could use. And although in recent times the opportunities for migra- tion have prevented the labourers from feeling the injurious results of that tendency, and wages and conditions have on the contrary steadily improved, they continue to leave the land. This is still partly to be attributed to the large farm system. For it deprived the labourers of their holdings, and so robbed agricultural employment of its chief attraction. The use of a piece of land makes the delights of town life look dull, and keeps the labourer in the country even when in many respects he might do better in other employments. The large farm system, therefore, aggravated the opposition between town and country conditions, and in every direction strengthened the tendency to migration. This fact has been recognised of late years, and in consequence the creation of small holdings has been regarded as of increasing importance as a means of putting a stop to the rural exodus. It is no longer simply a question of the need of the landed interests for allotments as a means of retaining their labourers. The movement is 1 Haggard, op. cit. Vol. I, pp. 105 f. (Sussex); Vol. II, p. 111 (Lincolnshire); p. in (Oxfordshire) ; and cp. also p. 539. 2 For such a description see Levy, Landarbeiterfrage etc., pp. 503-6; and also Shaw Lefevre, op. cit. pp. 31-33. Social and Political Aspects 117 not simply " in the interest of the employers," in the sense in which that is a doubtful benefit to the men. The question is understood to be a question of social policy. Small holdings and allotments are to bring the people back to the land. The aim of the Labourers' Friend Society in 1832 had been simply to improve the lot of the labourers, whose wages had fallen in view of the over-stocked market for their labour and the impossibility of migration. But the modern move- ment aims at moderating the rural exodus, and at re-populating the deserted country. It is very credible that labourers who are in a position to cultivate a bit of land for themselves are more inclined to remain on the land than the mere proletarian. There is something very attractive to the labourer in the prospect of advancing from the status of an allotment-holder to that of a small farmer, and of finally being free from the necessity of working for an employer. He wants something better to look forward to than his weekly wage on a Saturday night, as Mr Winfrey put it1. In the most various cases the provision of allotments and small holdings has proved to be favourable to the increase of the population of a district, just as when they dis- appeared the rural population was found to migrate if possible*. " It is an established fact," says Mr Samuel, "that in the villages of England where small holdings are numerous the population rarely declines and often increases8." Statistics too may be cited in this connection. In the Census of Occupations, under the head " Farmers' Relatives assisting in the work of the Farm," the numbers fell from 111,704 in the year 1851 to 75,197 in the year 1881, but rose again to 89,165 between 1881 and 1901. These noteworthy figures are probably chiefly to be explained by the development of small holdings. Small farming needs, both absolutely and per acre, more labour than does large farming; and therefore, with the decrease in small farms between 1851 and 1 88 1, went a decrease in the number of farmers' relatives employed. Conversely such employment increased from the moment when large farming began to give way to small4. Therefore, also, as labourers were converted into allotment-holders and small farmers, the possibility of keeping not only themselves but their sons and daughters on the land increased. It was this fact which first turned 1 Report of Proceedings at the Fifth Congress of the Co-operative Alliance, 1907, p. 343. 1 Ibid., p. 369. See also W. J. Harris's paper in Land, its Attractions and Riches, 189*, I p. 3°*- ' 3 Samuel, op. cit. p. 104. 4 See also Druce, op. cit. pp. 3, 13. 1 1 8 Large and Small Holdings the attention of the Liberal party to the social importance of small holdings. The old attempt to provide the labourer with land to cultivate or to keep stock on was revived, after nearly a century of impotence, under the motto of "three acres and a cow1." Legislative, as well as private effort, gave it expression. Before discussing the legislative efforts in this direction, however, there are certain important facts to be taken into consideration. (b) The problem of landowners/tip in relation to the unit of holding. The multiplication of small holdings may take place in two ways ; namely either by a revival of small properties, i.e. by the purchase of land by small cultivators, or by the division of large farms into small ones, and the consequent replacing of the existing large farmers by a greater number of small farmers. In either case the question of land- ownership offers difficulties. If the object in view is the multiplication of small properties, it has first of all to be taken into consideration that relatively speaking very little land comes upon the market in England. The greater part of the land is entailed, and the owner is obliged to hand it on intact at his death to his eldest son or other legal heir. He cannot sell any of it, unless under the very unattractive conditions prescribed by the Settled Land Act of 1882. In any case, many such owners have no idea of selling, but only desire to buy land ; so that the ownership of the soil continually comes into fewer and fewer hands. It may be said that 50 per cent, of the land of England is owned by between two and three thousand persons. A further result of the system is that the actual process of sale becomes expensive, since the possibility of the existence of an entail makes it necessary for the seller to prove in each instance his right to alienate the land in question, which adds to the lawyer's charges. And if the quantity of land upon the market is limited in this way, the would-be small owner finds the price of it enhanced in another way. In no country is the possession of land so much desired for social and political reasons as in England. Landownership gives the rich man social standing, and very often the possibility of a political career ; and every great iron-master, ship- builder or manufacturer must needs have his country house just as the old county families have. Then there is the question of sport. In the case of most sales the advertisements in the newspapers will 1 F. Impey, Three Acres and a Cow, 1885. Social and Political Aspects 119 be found to contain some such important item as " shooting good " ; or "good shooting, hunting and fishing"; or "choice sporting estate." Obviously, the demand for land for such purposes as these, more especially in view of the limited supply, must raise its exchange value above the capitalised annual profit. Although the actual price of land may have fallen in the last two or three decades, the wealthy purchaser finds compensation for the small return obtainable for his , capital in the non-economic advantages of landownership. The rents \ may be small, but he has the satisfaction of being a landlord ; and so | long as this is his object, he is ready to pay more for the land than I its strictly economic value would warrant. "There are landlords holding even large estates to whom it is not a matter of serious issue whether they get any profit from their estates1 " : and there are others who find farming "the pleasantest of recreations, giving health and pleasure far beyond yachting and horses," even if the " farm accounts year by year show a substantial balance on the wrong side2." This difference between the capitalised annual profit and the exchange value is however a serious matter for the man who wants to buy a small property and to live on its produce. He has to pay, in the enhanced purchasing price, for a quality of the land which is of no value to him, since what he is concerned with is simply the economic possibilities of the holding. All this is especially true of the neighbourhood of large towns ; and as the excellent means of communication in England bring the townsman rapidly and cheaply into the country, the word " neighbourhood " is here of wide significa- tion. If the purchaser of a small dairy-farm of, say, 20 acres, has to pay, besides the price reckoned in the ordinary way upon the profits, a " super-price " determined by the amount which a city capitalist is willing to pay for the property as a shooting-box or country residence, it naturally becomes doubtful whether the small owner, even if he does well, will be able to get from the land an adequate return upon his capital. This is the great difficulty in the way of a revival of j small properties. But the development of small tenant-farming, by the cutting up of large farms into small, is also faced with difficulties arising out of the problem of landownership in England. These difficulties become burning questions where small agriculturists have not the capital for the purchase of land, but have the means and capacity to rent a small holding. The difficulty in this case arises from the fact that it 1 W. J. Maiden, The Conversion of Arable Land into Pasture, 1898, p. 25. 2 Haggard, op. cit. Vol. I, p. 160. I2O Large and Small Holdings depends on the will of the landlord to form small farms or not to form them. Their economic interest, in the present day, often demands that they should form them. The reason why they frequently nevertheless fail to do so is partly to be sought in the high initial expenditure required for the erection of farmhouses and outbuildings, the provision of a water-supply, and so forth. They are afraid of such an experiment. Often they hesitate to borrow the necessary capital ; or if they have it themselves, some other investment seems safer or more profitable. But still, so far as the hindrances to the division of large farms lie in purely economic considerations such as these, they might be regarded as not insuperable. If many landlords had the experience of Lord Harrowby, who had five and twenty offers for a holding of 23 acres, while for one of 1000 acres he could not find a single purchaser, enlightened self-interest might be trusted to bring them to the conclusion that they must surely if slowly cut up their estates into small holdings unless they wish to see them vastly diminished in value1. Probably such economic considerations would already have led to a much more rapid development of small holdings if other non-economic motives had not counteracted their effect. But here again it has to be remembered that to the English landowner the soil is not simply an instrument of production, out of which he seeks to obtain the highest returns possible ; its value to him is very largely in the social, political and sporting amenities which it offers. Small holdings, however, are much less favourable than large to sport and hunting. Lord Harrowby did indeed attempt to explain the antipathy of landlords to the development of small holdings purely on the ground of the expenditure involved, and laid before the Committee of 1906 calculations intended to prove this. But an incidental remark in his evidence speaks more eloquently than those hypothetical figures. " I think if you have a house with shooting it is a disadvantage to have a lot of little holdings all about the place — there is trespass and all that." He himself at that time reared, he said, 5000 pheasants on , his estates8. In many neighbourhoods the landlord is an opponent \ of small holdings for the reason that they demand the transformation j of arable into pasture, which is bad for partridge shooting. In Norfolk large districts were for some time let at an almost nominal rent, although some of the land was well suited for fruit and vegetable culture, and therefore for the formation of small holdings8. Nor is 1 Small Holdings Report, 1906, qu. 2387 and qu. 2439. J Ibid., qu. 1450. Cp. also qu. 2458, 2460. \ * J. Simpson, in The County Gentleman's Estate Book, 1903, p. 114. Social and Political Aspects 121 this the only non-economic motive which affects the landlord adversely to small holdings. The cutting up of large fields and pastures, or the multiplication of buildings, or even of houses with smoking chimneys, may offend his taste and his sense of pride in his estate. Again, many Conservatively-minded landlords are doubtful whether the new race of small farmers, mostly raised from the ranks of the mere labourers, will represent the political views of their squire as well as the old true-blue large farmers ; or whether the creation of these new holdings may not create a crowd of radical land-reformers on their own preserves. This alone is sufficient to make many landlords prefer lowering the rent of their existing tenants to cutting up the farms with a view to obtaining a larger income. But their leanings in this direction are strongly confirmed by the influence of their land- agents. These latter have to administer the estates, to collect the rents and to treat with the tenants. The landlord, who spends his time hunting and shooting, the season in London, the winter in Paris or on the Riviera, has comparatively little time on his own land, and knows little of its economic aspects. He consults his agent on such points ; and the agent is in favour of large holdings. The large farmer is of the same social standing as himself, often his personal friend, and all difficult questions can be settled between them over a sociable glass of whisky. The trouble begins when the small farmer has to be dealt with1. In this case the tenant regards the agent as a capitalist rent-collector ; the agent regards the tenant as little better than a proletarian. Consequently their relations tend to be strained. Besides this, one holding of 300 acres gives the agent considerably less trouble, less controversy over repairs and such matters, than the same area when cut up into say fifteen holdings of 20 acres eachj The large farmer does small repairs for himself; to the little farmei every job seems big enough for a call upon the landlord. Hence the dislike of the agents for small holdings : and they have as a rule the ear of their employer. It must not however be forgotten that there' are honourable exceptions to this rule. There are wide-minded or energetic landlords (as for example the present President of the Board of Agriculture, Lord Carrington) and agents under such landlords who are really interested in carrying out their views1. But on the 1 The statement in the (distinctly Conservative) Report of 1906 that " of the agents who appeared before the Committee none expressed themselves as hostile to the creation of small holdings" is a somewhat naive defence in face of the facts, which are unfortunately only too well-known. The land-agents naturally do not ascribe their prejudice to mere selfishness, but to purely technical and economic considerations. * Small Holdings Report, 1906, Minutes, qu. 8059 (Mr J. Tomkinson) : and the evidence of Mr H. M. Jonas, agent for Lord Carrington, pp. 358 ff. 122 Large and Small Holdings whole the bitter words of that old Parliamentarian, Sir Francis Channing, are true : " It is an age of extreme luxury, when estates are bought by the enormously rich for social prestige, and without thought of the duty that attaches to the owner of land as the nation's trustee. With many, the passion for sport overrides everything, and will throw every obstacle in the way of sub-division, which endangers the interests of shooting or of hunting1." Yet a third class of opponents of small holdings is formed by the large farmers themselves, who are also strongly opposed to the letting of allotments to labourers. Their objections seem to be only partly due to the considerations of political or social advantage or general amenity which are at the root of the opposition of landlords and land- agents. They claim that their dislike is in the main based on economic considerations : and their arguments are those which their predeces- sors employed before them. They say that allotments will make the labourer too independent, and will lead him to expend more and better labour on his own holding than on theirs. Their ideal is still a proletarian labouring class, as appears in every discussion on small holdings and the rural exodus2. Yet it would seem a matter for serious consideration on their part whether, in view of the exodus from the land and the much-lamented shortage of labour, it would not suit them better to have labourers holding land than no labourers at all. Would not a constant supply of labour and the retention of the young men on the land be better than insufficient numbers of ageing men ? Kentish farmers are said to engage all manner of people from the towns nearest to them for their harvest work — clerks, petty officials, etc., who spend their holidays in this manner and so combine pleasure with profit. It hardly seems reasonable that farmers in such a position should grudge the labourer his allotment, instead of rejoicing at a means which would put labour at his disposal when he needed it. The smallest holdings keep the younger labourers on the soil and so would supply him with regular daily labour. The larger allotments should provide the necessary occasional labour, especially where they consist of grass land, and the wife is able to look after the cow-sheds and milk the cows when her husband is out at work. It is frequently reported that such allotment-holders make the best labourers3. In short, the economic objections of the large farmer seem to be rather a traditional prejudice than a genuine argu- ment, even if they are made in good faith, which is often doubtful. 1 Small Holdings Report, 1906, p. 53. 2 Cp. e.g. Proceedings of the Central Chamber of Agriculture, 1901, p. 116. 3 Earl of Onslow, op. cit. p. 47. Social and Political Aspects 123 Their dislike is really traceable to social considerations, which for purposes of discussion are decently cloaked in economic garments. As a matter of fact the large farmer has an antipathy to the small man who claims or hopes to claim a position of independence. It is largely due to this social prejudice that, as Mr Channing's Minority Report put it : " The majority of the large farmers do not yet seem to realise what the systematic development of allotments and small holdings can do for agriculture in maintaining on the spot a perma- nent supply of efficient and skilled labour1." The prejudices of the large farmers and land-agents also mutually strengthen each other. Mr G. C. Brodrick drew from such considerations as these the conclusion that small holdings cannot make much progress unless the great landed estates are broken up. Where the estate is com- paratively small and the owner is his own agent the evils resulting from the free hand given to the agent on the large estates are not, he says, present; and on such estates the tendency to divide the holdings is stronger2. No doubt the abolition of primogeniture and of entails would be favourable both to the breaking up of large estates and to the development of small holdings. But the division of the large farms is making good progress in England in spite of the present conditions of land-owning. The social and political counteracting tendencies just described do indeed hinder, but do not prevent, the economically profitable development. This, however, is a fact which deserves some attention. For the first time in English agrarian history, the system of capitalistic concentration, as applied to the land, is showing serious weakness. So far, it has developed hand in hand with the economic needs of agriculture. Large estates and large farms went excellently together. At the present time the interest of the landowner, economically speaking, would be in the formation of small farms. But his interests are only partly economic. They are also social and political, and to these latter the small farm system does not correspond. The social and political interests, moreover, are often as strong as, or even stronger than, the desire to obtain the highest possible money return. Here lies the danger for the future de- velopment of English agriculture, and the defect of the hitherto economically satisfactory system of capitalist agriculture. If land- owners prize the non-economic aspects of their estates so highly as to 1 Final Report, 1897, p. 355. 2 Brodrick, op. cit. pp. 393 f. " The owner of many thousand acres... is almost sure to be more or less in the hands of his agent," etc. 124 Large and Small Holdings be willing to pay a considerable price for them ; if on political grounds, or from negligence, carelessness or ignorance they prefer to lower the rents of their large corn-growing tenants rather than to support those tenants who are prepared to wring greater results from the soil by the sweat of their brows, then they have certainly become monopolists of the worst type, and from an economic point of view are a superfluous class. Every modification of rent allowed to a corn-growing farmer on land where small holdings would make a greater profit is a premium offered by the landowner for the maintenance of an economically retrograde agriculture. Land has so far become a luxury. It pro- duces, with the help of privately provided bounties in the form of lowered rents, commodities, such as corn, which could be imported more cheaply from abroad ; whereas if managed on purely capitalist principles it would only produce commodities in which it could com- pete on equal terms with the foreigner. Such is the conflict between the problem of the proper unit of holding and the problem of landownership as the two stand in England at present : and so much it has been necessary to premise in order to explain the origin of the movement which from 1880 onwards has demanded the multiplication of small holdings by means of State interference. The measures passed for this purpose, and above all the Small Holdings Act of 1907, may well be described as measures of agrarian reform. For they are attempts to reform the present conditions of landownership in England in so far as they have been found a hindrance to a healthy development of agricultural small holdings. CHAPTER VIII LEGISLATIVE ACTION IN FAVOUR OF SMALL HOLDINGS (a) The Small Holdings Acts. THE series of Acts aiming at the formation of small holdings begins first of all with Acts for the creation of allotments. Such are the Allotments Act of 1887 (50 and 51 Viet. c. 48) and the Allotments Act of 1890 (53 and 54 Viet. c. 65). There follows the most significant Act of the series, the Small Holdings Act of 1 892 (55 and 56 Viet. c. 3 1 ), aimed exclusively at the creation of small holdings, whereas the Local Government Act of 1894 (56 and 57 Viet. c. 73) is only of importance as regards allotments, and therefore hardly concerns us here. Finally comes the last and most important measure, the Small Holdings and Allotments Act of 1907 (7 Ed. VII. c. 54), amending that of 1892, and aiming at a fundamental reform of the previous methods of State creation both of small tenancies and small properties. It was preceded by the Report of the Departmental Committee appointed by the Board of Agriculture, which sat in 1905 and 1906, and took much evidence as to the results and failures of the previous Acts. This Committee consisted of men of the highest qualifications as authorities on agri- culture or agricultural policy, among whom were the former President of the Board of Agriculture, Lord Onslow ; its present President, Lord Carrington, whose services to the small holdings' movement have already been mentioned ; the well-known champion of " three acres and a cow," Mr Jesse Collings ; Major Craigie, the official agricultural statistician; Mr R. A. Yerburgh, M.P., the pioneer of agricultural co-operation in England ; Sir F. A. Channing, and others. Among the expert witnesses who appeared before it were small farmers, land-agents, landlords, and various authorities on agricultural policy ; but, unfortunately, no agricultural labourers. The Majority Report (signed only with certain reservations by some members) was presented to the President of the Board on December 10, 1906. But 126 Large and Small Holdings its recommendations were only in part the basis of the Bill of 1907, since the change of government which took place in the meantime naturally meant that the Bill, when introduced, would represent the views of the Liberal Party, which differed essentially from those of the Committee and the Report. The Small Holdings Bill of the Liberal Party it was which became law on August 28, 1907. To understand the whole significance of this measure it is necessary to outline the provisions of the Act of 1892, which the new Act amended. Those provisions were briefly as follows: — Every County Council was empowered to create small holdings if a sufficient demand were proved to exist; that is to say, if any person laid a petition to that effect before the Council, and the Council convinced itself that there was such a demand. The State was to provide the necessary capital for the purchase of land at a low rate of interest, but the purchaser must pay down on the spot at least \ of the price. He might leave upon the land a perpetual rent equal to the interest on \ of the remaining capital ; but the other f was to be paid off in half- yearly instalments of principal and interest. Where the applicant was not in a position to purchase land, the Council might let a small holding to him. But such a holding was not to be more than 1 5 acres in area, nor of a higher value than would be represented by a rent of £15 per annum. The main object was thus the creation of small properties and not of small tenancies. The result of this legislation by no means corresponded to the hopes of its promoters. Although the Act obliged every County Council to form a Committee to receive and consider petitions, and although such petitions were received in 27 counties of England and Wales and 14 Scottish counties, in the ten years 1892 to 1902 only 652 acres had been acquired for the purposes of the Act. Only five English counties and one Scottish county bought land, and three English counties rented land, for small holdings. Between 1902 and 1906 only two cases were known in which an English County Council had purchased land under the Act. In one case 46 acres, in the other 92 acres had been bought. The question arises as to why so promising a measure failed to accomplish the "home colonisation" expected of it. The most natural explanation would be that the legislation corresponded to no economic need. But neither the witnesses before the Committee of 1905-6 nor the Report of the Committee gives any countenance to such an hypothesis. On the contrary, the whole enquiry showed plainly that a lively demand for small holdings Legislative Action 127 existed throughout the country, and that any practicable method of facilitating their revival would be more than ever welcome from an economic point of view1. If no explanation of the failure of the Act of 1892 is to be found in this direction, then the next possibility which will suggest itself will be that the disappointing result was due to some inadequacy in the administration of the Act. The Report of 1906 pointed to this as a possibility; and undoubtedly with justification. Sometimes special reasons would lead a County Council to leave the Act unused. In one county, where no less than 349 petitions were received, "it was decided that as 'the rate-payers were already burdened with heavy taxation it was unfair to impose upon them the extra cost of carrying out the Act, an experiment which ought to be borne by the State2.'" In many cases it was difficult to gauge the strength of the demand for small holdings. Many of those who were quite likely to desire them remained ignorant of the existence of the Act. In Worcestershire, Norfolk and Lincolnshire the application of the Act was traceable to the initiative of certain enthusiastic members of the County Council, and their action was fully justified. The Report of 1906, which was in favour of leaving the main principles of the law unchanged, laid special emphasis on these cases, as showing that the difficulties were only difficulties of administration. It proposed that a Central Board should share the administrative powers with the local authorities, a proposal which was incorporated in the Bill ultimately introduced, and now appears as the first part of the new Act (sections i-5). According to these sections, the Board of Agriculture is to act as central authority for this purpose. It appoints certain Small Holdings Commissioners, i.e. officials who are to seek to ascertain what demand there is for small holdings in the various counties and how far it appears practicable and desirable to satisfy this demand. It is an important point that not merely the County Councils, but also the smaller bodies, the District and Parish Councils, are able to supply the Commissioners with materials on which to form their judgment, so that the County Councils, which have so often shown themselves disinclined to take the matter up, are no longer the sole judges of the questions at issue. If the Board of Agriculture considers that the creation of small holdings in a certain district is desirable and 1 Small Holdings Report, 1906, Minutes, pp. 444 and 445 of the index. Cp. also the instructive book by Miss Jebb (now Mrs Wilkins) on The Small Holdings of England, 1907, passim. z Small Holdings Report, 1906, p. n, § 46. 128 Large and Small Holdings practicable, it can require the County Council to produce a detailed scheme for the purpose. If the Council fails to fulfil this duty, the Board itself may prepare such a scheme, obtaining the necessary information by means of a public enquiry, as it can always do in the case of a difference of opinion between itself and a County Council. The scheme must then be carried out, according to the Acts of 1892 and 1907, by the County Council. If the Council again refuses to do its duty, the Commissioners may take over the work, and in that case all rights given by the Acts to the County Council pass to the Commissioners, but the County Council or other local authority concerned is responsible for the expenditure incurred. It is evident that these provisions put upon the County Council the pressure which has so far been wanting. That the smaller local authorities, which hitherto have had to proceed through the County Council, can now appeal direct to the central authority (see Part III, 26 (7) of the Act of 1907), which is to be carefully and constantly observant of the whole question, is in itself a great step in advance: and the fact that in case of need the Commissioners can take action at last provides a guarantee that any really well-founded demand for small holdings will be satisfied. Nevertheless it would be a mistake to ascribe the miscarriage of the Act of 1892 solely to the failure of County Councils to carry it into effect. In spite of the anxiety of the Departmental Committee to put that cause in the forefront, it could not be concealed, in view both of the evidence of experts and the facts they brought forward, that the whole machinery of the Act was defective, and in parts faulty, and that some of its most essential features needed radical reform. This was especially the case with the provisions respecting the acquisition of land. Even where a Council did not lack the goodwill and the energy necessary to carry out the Act, it was powerless to proceed if there were no land suitable for division at its disposal. "Large farms, it is true, come into the market from time to time," wrote a man of experience, Mr C. R. Buxton, in a memorandum which is well worth reading1, "but small quantities of land are often quite impossible to obtain." The conditions noted above as enhancing the value of land in England increase the difficulty in this case also; it is indeed partly created by the long-established customs and traditions of English landownership. The exchange value of a large estate is, for social and political reasons, higher than the price which small 1 Small Holdings Report, 1906, Minutes, p. 431. Legislative Action 129 agriculturists can afford to pay for it when cut up into areas of 5 to 50 acres. In particular, the landowner hopes, by selling a com- paratively large extent of land to some wealthy man, fond of sport and not particular about making a profit on the estate, to get for those parts of the land which are of little value for agricultural purposes a price which it will indeed be worth the while of such a purchaser to pay, from his point of view, but which no mere agri- culturist could afford. When the Small Holdings Bill of 1892 was before Parliament, a member of an eminent firm of land-agents wrote a letter to the Press, quoted by Mr Shaw Lefevre1, in which he stated: — "My firm has on its books for sale a considerable number " of landed properties of from 1,000 to 10,000 acres or more. In most " of them the land lies together, and many of them consist of a whole " parish, or of two or three adjoining parishes. It cannot be expected " that in these cases the vendors will be willing to sell to local "authorities 50 or 100 acres... for the purpose of creating a number "of small freeholders or leaseholders — The entirety of a property "within its boundaries is a great attraction to purchasers. The " planting of a number of small freeholders in the midst of it might " greatly interfere with the amenities of the estate, as they are generally " understood, and with the sporting rights over the same. We have "many other smaller properties for sale, of ioo to IOOO acres. Most " of these are of a residential character, where we could not advise " vendors to sell off part for the creation of small ownerships." It was therefore no wonder that in a report on the Act of 1892, published in 1895, the complaint was made that the County Councils were hardly anywhere in a position to obtain land. Either it was not to be had at all, or not upon reasonable terms. On the other hand it was a perfectly justifiable provision of the Act that land should not be bought unless the price was such that it could be repaid by the small agriculturist who was to be the ultimate purchaser (cf. Section 18(1)). The County Council was consequently obliged to avoid paying more for the land than its capitalised annual value. But in the result it was often impossible to purchase at all. Thus in one Lincolnshire parish containing 21,133 acres, only 146 acres were available for the purposes of the Act. It was on the ground of this experience that a demand for compulsory purchase began to be heard on all sides. When in 1892 the Small Holdings Bill of that year was under discussion in and outside Parliament, there was no possibility of carrying such a clause, 1 Shaw Lefevre, op. cit. p. 268. L. 9 130 Large and Small Holdings though the idea had been carefully considered by the original pro- moters of the Bill. The Conservative Party would never have con- sented to such a thing. In their view the contemplated legislation might be a useful means of keeping a greater proportion of the rural population on the land, but they would have nothing to do with anything which might recall the attacks of Land Reformers upon the rights of property. "I myself am strongly against compulsion," said Lord Salisbury in February 1892, "at all events at this stage; because I do not believe it to be needed, and because I am sure that com- pulsion will create ill-will1." Lord Salisbury thus left it to experience to prove the necessity for compulsion. The evidence which he demanded was certainly not slow to appear. Even by 1893 Mr Shaw Lefevre, in his excellent book on Agrarian Tenures, was able to say "there is little hope of obtaining such land, unless power to purchase it by compulsion be conferred on local authorities2." The Liberal Party were from that time forward zealous advocates of the intro- duction of provision for compulsion. Mr Herbert Samuel, in his book on Liberalism, published in 1902, describes this as the most important necessary reform in the Act of 1892. The results of the Committee of Enquiry of 1905-6, as already indicated, confirm the proposition. In fact, the system of compulsory purchase had already amply justified itself in the case of the creation of allotments, where, under the Allotments Acts and the Local Government Act of 1894, the District and Parish Councils could either buy or rent land compulsorily, if so instructed by the County Council. These Acts had obviously been much more effective than the Small Holdings Act. Between 1887 and 1897, 12,516 acres had been acquired under the Allotments Acts by the local authorities, and 3785 acres between 1897 and 1902. No doubt the question of allotments depends on other considerations of agricultural and rural economy than the question of small holdings, and the chances of the multiplication of the former were originally better. But the difficulty of acquiring land is common to both problems: so that the working of the Allotments Acts clearly proved that the possibility of com- pulsory purchase by the authority concerned could considerably lessen that difficulty. It had also proved, however, that the possibility of compulsion by 1 Quoted in Shaw Lefevre, op. cit. p. 86. 2 Ibid., p. 273. It is remarkable that Mr Shaw Lefevre (now Lord Eversley) advocated as long ago as 1893 precisely the measures which have now become law ; cp. op. cit. pp. 170-173. Legislative Action 131 no means necessarily meant that resort would be had to that weapon. Between 1897 and 1902, 3576 acres were acquired by the Councils by way of agreement with the landowners, and only 206 by compulsion1. Various cases were brought to the notice of the Committee of 1905-6 where "the mere existence of the (compulsory) powers has secured the provision of land where otherwise none would have been forth- coming2." The possibility of expropriation put pressure upon the landowner. It also prevented the evil often complained of before the Committee, that the price of land offered to the authorities was often far above the " fair market price." For if this happened to be the case the Council could use their powers of compulsion. It was thus a simple statement of fact when Sir F. A. Channing wrote that "com- pulsory powers, if too costly for frequent use, at least tend to bring about acquisition by agreement3." Even the Conservatively-minded Majority Report could not leave this proposition out of account. But it confined itself to the suggestion that such powers should be vested in the central authority, namely the Board of Agriculture, and only in the case of purchase. Even that, however, was a step forward, as compared with Lord Salisbury's pronouncement of fourteen years earlier. The Liberal Bill went further. It did not take the Committee's view that the right of expropriation should be confined to the central Department, which would be unlikely to use it "arbitrarily4." On the contrary, section 6(2) of the new Act provides that "If a County Council are unable to acquire by agreement and on reasonable terms suitable land for the purpose aforesaid, they may acquire land compulsorily in accordance with the provisions of this Act." This power, as has been shown above, passes in case of need to the central authority. It includes the right of compulsory hiring, as well as of purchase. And in the former possibility lies hid the most significant and decisive reform of the whole measure. For the great hindrance to the effectiveness of the Act of 1892 had obviously not lain simply in the fact that the County Councils found it difficult to acquire land. From the very first, experience under the Act brought a second problem to the fore: namely, whether the purchase of land by the local authority and the formation of small properties rather than small tenancies is the best means to pursue for the revival of small holdings in England. 1 Return to the House of Commons, May 18, 1903 (Local Government Board), p. i*. 1 Small Holdings Report, 1906, Minutes, p. 432. 8 Ibid., p. 53, § 13. « Ibid., p. 33, § 43. 9—2 132 Large and Small Holdings The pioneers of the whole movement were two men who at that time were prominent Radicals, namely Mr Joseph Chamberlain and Mr Jesse Collings. In a very interesting publication of the year 1885, which bore the imprimatur of Mr Chamberlain and was entitled The Radical Programme, it was expressly stated that — "It will be found that in a rich country like England, with the desire for land which is generally found among the wealthy classes, there will be but small chance for either farmers or labourers who are not capitalists to raise themselves out of the ranks of tenants and wage-receivers. Some special legislation will be needed to prevent monopoly and accumula- tion of land by a few persons, and to bring about, or rather to restore, the interest and connection between the cultivator and the soil which exist in other countries, and which in former times obtained in Eng- land. Occupying ownership and peasant proprietary established under certain conditions and by the aid of the State, acting through local authorities, seem to be the direction in which these objects can best be secured1." Peasant proprietorship was thus the aim of the first promoters of the movement : and accordingly the Act of 1892 favoured the creation of small properties rather than of small tenancies. Such tenancies, it will be remembered, might not be of greater extent than 15 acres (whereas small properties might be anything up to 50 acres), and then might only be let if the County Council was of opinion that the prospective tenant was not in a position to purchase such a holding. But in spite of the intentions of the pioneers and the provisions of the Act, the expectations of a revival of small ownership were dis- appointed to a very remarkable degree. Of the 569 acres of land acquired by the County Councils between 1892 and 1902, only 162 had been sold to their occupiers, whereas 373 were let. The explanation is not obscure. The interposition of the local authority did indeed facili- tate the acquisition of land by the small agriculturist in many ways; but it did not do away with the fundamental difficulty, viz. that he had to pay, in the exchange value of the land, more than its capitalised annual value. Also, though he only had to pay down \ of the total price, that sum was no inconsiderable one, especially as, if the Council provided the necessary buildings, etc., \ of their cost was included. Or if the preparation of the holding was not undertaken by the Council, then the purchaser had to be prepared with a still larger amount of capital. He must also be provided with the necessary working capital ; so that merely to take over such a property would 1 The Radical Programme, 1885, pp. 145 f. Legislative Action 133 demand a sum of ready money which would be more than most of the persons in question would possess. The amount may be reckoned at about .£400 for a holding of 30 acres; and the small holder would then still have the annual instalments of the remainder of the purchase-money as a considerable burden lying upon him for the future. But if the purchase of a holding thus makes demands upon the capital of the small agriculturist which he either cannot meet or does not consider it worth his while to incur, he is on the other hand much more frequently in a position to invest his capital profitably in renting a small farm. If the County Council can take land at the usual rent, and will re-let it to the small man at a rent only so much higher as corresponds to the expenditure incurred, the latter is as a rule quite able so to increase the profitableness of the holding as to pay the enhanced rent. He can then apply his whole capital as working capital, instead of sinking it in the land. A witness before the Committee of 1906, Mr H. H. Smith, sets out very intelligibly the considerations which affect the small agriculturist on the taking over of a small holding : — " He does not look forward like the French " peasant. County Council Committees who have sat to hear appli- " cations for land under the Small Holdings Act have been sadly "disappointed to find what a very small number of the applicants " were willing to accept their holdings under the purchase system : by " far the greater number of them are desirous of renting only, and that " for short terms, the general desire being for a yearly tenancy. This " may possibly have arisen from the fact that the future of agriculture " in this country is still uncertain ; and no one can say that we have " touched the bottom of the depression. Therefore the labourer who " aspires to become a small farmer may hesitate to embark his earnings " in an enterprise which binds him to a fixed rent, which rent must be " paid, whether matters get worse or not... For the English peasant to " become a proprietor under the existing Act means that he will for fifty " years — that is the whole stretch of his life — have to pay a greater sum " annually for the land which he is to make his freehold, than if he were " merely renting it ; in addition to this he has to find a sum to be paid " down representing one-fifth of the purchase-money. His proprietary " instincts are not strong, and he does not care to pinch himself in "order to benefit posterity. Moreover he argues 'the capital I am " finding as part purchase-money of my holding if added to the money " I must necessarily find to stock it, will enable me to take a larger " farm as a leasing or renting tenant, than I can possibly take under the 134 Large and Small Holdings " purchase system : I will therefore go for leasing, because I can get a " bigger income for myself A Frenchman will probably argue the "other way, and say: 'True, under the purchasing system I can only " take a smaller holding than I could under the leasing system, but I " am saving money under the first system in a sure and almost im- " perceptible manner, as every day I am nearing the time when the " holding will become a freehold which I shall be able to bequeath to " my family.' This apparently does not appeal to the English peasants, " and the passion for ownership does not exist among them to any- thing like the same extent that it does in many other nations1." It is a curious fact that the last remnants of the lesser yeomanry disappeared in the period 1760 to 1815, because, in view of the high price of corn then ruling, the small man found it more profitable to take a large holding as farmer than to retain his position as a small owner. He sold his land, attracted by the higher income to be made on an arable farm of some hundreds of acres. The economics of the unit of holding were the determining factor in that movement. But it is not any question as to the unit of holding which causes the small capitalist of the present day to prefer tenancy to ownership. A small holding is now more profitable than a large holding. The determin- ing factor today is the problem of ownership itself, namely the contrast between the exchange value of the land and the comparatively small return to be obtained from it The Departmental Committee could not well ignore the various cases cited and expressions of opinion given in proof of this tendency to prefer tenancy to ownership. The Report mentions yet other causes making in the same direction ; e.g. a fear on the part of the small capitalist that some new agricultural crisis might depreciate the value of his land after he had bought it; the difficult question of inheritance; the desire of small agriculturists to begin with a few acres only, but to be able to increase their holdings as their savings grow, an aspiration more easily fulfilled by a tenant than by a proprietor. These are all no doubt real elements in the preference for tenancy, though the relatively high cost of land is certainly its main cause. The Committee, however, did not draw the conclusion that the Act of 1892 should be so amended as to correspond to the actual needs of the day. On the contrary, it held fast to the principles of the old Act, and only recommended certain changes directed to facilitate the purchase of small holdings. Its argument was that the great advantage to be expected from such 1 Small Holdings Report, 1906, Minutes, qu. 3733. Legislative Action 135 legislation could only arise from the creation of a number of small holders with a permanent interest in the land and in their own soil. It had been proved, they said, "that in some parts of the country the 'magic of property' is entirely appreciated. It was pointed out that a man who can give a year's notice to his landlord is much more likely to be attracted to the towns than one whose all is invested in the piece of land which he cultivates, and that a small occupying freeholder will gladly do the work of two labourers for the earnings of one1." Arthur Young, writing in the early years of the nineteenth century of his visit to the small proprietors of the Isle of Axholme, had spoken of "the magic of property" as there manifested. This phrase has sent his name down to posterity as that of a champion of peasant pro- prietorship, though as a matter of fact he was the most zealous of advocates for capitalist large farming. Wherever the creation of small properties is in question in England to-day, there that classic phrase does duty. It naturally appears, therefore, in the Report of 1906. "The magic of property," it is there claimed, though not every- where present in the England of to-day, might very well be developed among small agriculturists. It might also be used as a means to bind the countryman to the soil and to prevent the depopulation of the rural districts. So far, in the Committee's opinion, "the advantages of ownership" had not as a rule "been sufficiently forcibly put before those who desire to cultivate land2." Therefore, in spite of experience, which was all against the possibility of the revival of peasant proprietorship on any consider- able scale, the Committee only recommended that the sum to be paid down by purchasers should be reduced from £ to ^, while it left un- touched the question of any facilitation of small tenancies. The proposal to offer landlords extensive facilities for borrowing from public funds would indeed, if carried out, have increased the possi- bility of the creation of such tenancies; but it would have had no bearing on their formation by the local authorities. This view of the Committee, that the Government should mainly concern itself with the provision of small properties only, was shared by, and indeed was largely based on the support of, Mr Jesse Collings, the original champion of the Act of 1892. He remains now as then a staunch upholder of the position that any multiplication of small holdings must be in the first place a multiplication of small properties. He protested in a Minority Report of his own against the Committee's 1 Small Holdings Report, 1906, p. 29, § 123; see also the whole section on Tenants or Freeholders, pp. 28-30. 2 Ibid., pp. 29 f. 136 Large and Small Holdings proposal to give credit to the landlords, and emphasised, on the other hand, the necessity for further measures favouring the creation of small ownership. These measures he also discussed in a book published in rox*)1, and embodied in a Bill brought in by him but never passed into law. But the advocacy of "occupying ownership " at least was common to him and to the Majority Report. From this view there naturally developed strong opposition to the system of compulsory hiring of land as advocated from the Liberal side for some years previously. Mr Ceilings' arguments on this point were prac- tically the same as those of the Report, which said that: — "The exercise of compulsory powers of this kind would involve the creation of a system of tenant right, under which the ownership of land would, in effect, be divided between two or even more persons and authorities. The result would be, in the opinion of the Com- mittee, that the sense of responsibility which should accompany ownership would cease to exist, and also that endless disputes and litigation would arise between landlords and tenants. Another result would be to provoke, quite unnecessarily, the hostility of all large farmers and landowners — Experience has proved that a system of dual ownership of land is one which, under ordinary economic con- ditions, cannot be permanent, and which, while it lasts, is fatal to the proper maintenance of holdings, to harmony between landlord and tenant, and to the prosperity of agriculture*." Some courage was required to appeal to this "sense of responsi- bility," in view of the fact that so many English landlords regard their land in the first place as a means of obtaining sport, social considera- tion, or political advantage; but the reference is a clear indication of the spirit by which the Report was inspired. So far as it recognised the principle of compulsion at all, namely only in the case of purchase and only by the authority of the central Department, it was where it could be of little value. It was much more important that the right of compulsion should be extended to the authority which first comes into play, i.e. the County Council; and that it should be available not only for the purchase, but also for the hire of land. These necessities were taken into account by the Liberal Bill and by the Act of 1907, and it may be said that it is precisely these provisions which give the Act its character as a genuine measure of reform. The Act of 1907, although it stands for the principle that the creation of small tenancies is to be favoured, by no means refuses to 1 Jesse Ceilings, Land Reform, 1906. J Small Holdings Report, 1906, p. 33, § 144. Legislative Action 137 forward the formation of small properties. But by the abolition of the limitation of small tenancies to an area of 15 acres and a rent of £15 (see section 4 (2) of the old Act) this form of holding is no longer put at a disadvantage : and, as already stated, the right of compulsion is extended to the case of hiring as well as to that of purchase. In both cases it is naturally provided that the right shall only be exercised "if a County Council are unable to acquire by agreement and on reason- able terms suitable land for the purpose" (sec. 6 (2) and sec. 22). Naturally also land which is not to be considered as in agricultural occupation is exempted from the possibility of compulsory acquisition. The limitations under this head (see section 30) are very extensive. They apply to parks, gardens, recreation grounds, home farms, etc., so that the landlord cannot be expropriated from any of his proper "demesne-lands." But as, in other cases, purchase as well as hiring is included in the provisions for compulsion, and as on the other hand hiring is no longer put at a disadvantage as compared with purchase when the procedure is by agreement, it seems probable that the choice as between hiring and buying will in future be decided mainly on the ground of the economic needs in the particular case. This important provision for compulsory hiring necessitated a number of minor regulations, of which some account must be given here. The hiring must be by way of lease, for not less than fourteen or more than thirty-five years (section 26 (2)). But the authority may, by observing certain terms of notice, renew the lease for another period of at least fourteen or at most thirty-five years, again com- pulsorily, if an agreement cannot be arrived at (section 27 (i)). To determine the rent to be paid by the authority to the owner, the valuer is to keep in view the following points (see Schedule I, Part II (4)): — (i) the rent at which the land has hitherto been let, and the value at which it is assessed for rating purposes, (2) the loss (if any) falling upon the owner in consequence of the division of a holding, (3) the length and other conditions of the lease. Under this head any reservations made by the landlord, as of rights of hunting or fishing, are to be taken into account. (4) But there shall not be taken into account any future increment of value for any purpose other than that under consideration, in so far as the landlord has the right to demand the land back for such expressly defined purposes. That is to say that if a landlord, within the duration of the lease, wants his land, or a part of it, for building, mining or any other industrial purpose, it will, under certain conditions, be put at his disposal (section 33 (i)); so that there is no need to take 138 Large and Small Holdings account of such possibilities in setting the rent. Provision is also made for a re-valuation for the purpose of determining the rent if the lease is renewed (section 27 (2)). The valuer is not to take into account (i) improvements for which the authority could have demanded compensation in case it had not renewed the lease. (2) Any increased value of the holding arising from possible other uses to which the landlord might put it within the duration of the lease, in so far as he has the right to reclaim the land for such purposes. (3) Any increased value arising from the fact that the authority has created other small holdings in the neighbourhood. (4) Any decrease of value for which the landlord could have claimed compensation from the authority in case the lease had not been renewed. It will be seen that the aim of these regulations is so to fix the rent that throughout the lease the landlord may be receiving about the sum he was receiving before the Council took over the land. Any increase of value which may arise from the creation of the small holdings upon it belongs to the Council, or, if the latter so arranges, to the small holder. In this way it was sought to meet the fear so often expressed that any such enhanced value would in the long run simply fall to the landowner in the form of an increased rent. But if at the termination of a lease the land is again placed at the disposal of the owner the further question arises as to the manner in which the Council or its tenant is to be compensated for improve- ments. The Act provides (section 35 (2)) that for this purpose the Agricultural Holdings Acts of 1883-1906 shall apply, and that "the amount of compensation payable to the Council for those improve- ments shall be such sum as fairly represents the increase (if any) in the value to the landlord and his successors in title of the holding due to those improvements." These Acts aim at ensuring to any outgoing tenant proper compensation for his expenditure and im- provements. But it has been found by no means easy to guarantee to such tenants easy and effective settlement of their complicated claims. Even the latest measures have not satisfied the representatives of the farming interest, as may be seen by a resolution passed at a recent meeting of the Central Chamber of Agriculture1: — " That the Agricultural Holdings Act being the basis on which farming is conducted, should be so amended that the capital which the farmer invests in his holding is as safe as if the holding belonged to him, and that nothing should stand in the way of the tenant making the land produce all it can." " This resolution is well conceived," 1 Cited by Ceilings, op. cit. p. 244. Legislative Action 139 comments Mr Jesse Collings, "but it is absolutely impossible to carry it into law. The question is full of complications. A farmer may be a man of good judgment or bad, and to enact that he should receive compensation on leaving his farm for all that he has done, without the consent of his landlord, in the way of what he considers to be improvement, would lead to difficulties, and certainly to litigation. Some of the outlay he had made might be considered by an incoming tenant, as well as by the landlord, as useless or of small value. Other work, such as the planting of orchards, etc., would require some years to show whether or not it was worth paying for at all1." It must be remembered, however, in reading Mr Ceilings' comments, that to him, as a champion of small ownership, the present failure to satisfy the claimants of tenants' right is a useful weapon for attack upon the whole system of tenancy. Things are not quite so bad as he sees them. But still it is obvious that this question of compensation does offer peculiar difficulties in the case of small holdings. For the small farmer is probably a poor man, to whom every shilling sunk in his land represents much more than it does to the well-to-do large farmer; it is generally recognised that he improves the land, by his more intensive methods, much more than the large farmer does ; while on the other hand, being as a rule a man of comparatively little education, he is hardly in a position to realise and enforce his rights. If it is attempted to give him protection by means of special legislation, as in the case of the Market Gardeners' Compensation Act, a danger arises that the landlord will be still less inclined to create such holdings, for fear of having to pay down large sums in compensation to his tenants at the end of their lease. This tendency is aggravated when, as in the particular Act cited, such compensation has to be paid for improvements undertaken without the landlord's consent. The difficulty of the question, however, is considerably mitigated when a mediating body, namely the local authority, intervenes between the landlord and the tenant. For it is to be supposed that the Council, upon which will fall the duty of compensating the small farmer on his giving up his holding, will recognise his just claims more readily than would the landowner himself; and that the tenant will find it easier to get those claims settled than if he himself had to treat with his landlord. It is specially important to note that the Act of 1907 enacts that the provisions of the Market Gardeners' Compensation Act shall be applied to all small holdings created by local authorities, so that their tenants can demand compensation for 1 Ceilings, loc. cit. 140 Large and Small Holdings improvements made without their consent, unless they had expressly prohibited the improvement in question (see section 35 (i)). The landowner in his turn becomes liable for such improvements, so far as they have actually increased the value of his land, when the Council's lease comes to an end. When all these implications of compulsory hiring of land are taken into consideration, a circumstance which at first sight seemed surprising becomes quite comprehensible; namely, that the great majority of English landlords, together with the closely-connected Conservative Party, fought much more strenuously against compulsory hiring than against compulsory purchase. Even the Committee of 1905-6, as has been noticed above, was prepared to come to terms with the principle of compulsory purchase: but it was hotly opposed to any idea of compulsory hiring. It was this point, too, that met with the strongest opposition from the Conservatives when the Bill was before Parliament. For, as will be now evident to the reader, compulsory hiring meant that the landlord would be stripped of his right to set the conditions of a lease at his pleasure1. The greater part of the demand made under the name of " the three Fs " is thus indirectly conceded. These " Three Fs " consist in a series of principles which have been incorporated in the land laws of Ireland, and which certain reformers have from about 1890 onwards desired to see applied to English conditions also. They concern (i) Fair Rent ; that is to say the fixing of rents by authority at an amount which will leave a suitable amount of profit to the tenant ; (2) Fixity of Tenure ; i.e. provision that a tenant who cultivates his land reasonably well and duly pays his rent may not be given notice to quit ; and finally (3) Free Sale ; i.e. the right of the out-going tenant to demand from his successor compensation for improvements made by him, or in some way to be able, on leaving the farm, to treat such improve- ments as saleable property. The Conservative Party in England has strongly protested against these demands in the interests of the landed aristocracy, using the argument that to concede them would create a divided property in land, and that in consequence the relation between landlord and tenant would be vitiated. On the other hand the demand has developed specially strongly among 1 A characteristic expression of the landlord's point of view is to be found in the Estate Book, 1908, p. 56: — " Compulsory sale is often hardship enough, though it is necessary in certain circumstances ; but to recognise a man's right of property in land, and yet to take it out of his control, and to keep it or return it at will is tyranny and injustice " (Mr Bear). Legislative Action 141 the small farmers, who are naturally interested in every attack upon the right of the owner to do what he will with his own land. They recognise that as tenants they are in a worse position relatively to the landlord than are the large farmers. Large farmers, at the present day, are comparatively few and are therefore sought after. When they come to take a farm, they are often met by no competitors. They can therefore dictate their terms in a way im- possible to the small farmer, faced as he is in many cases by twenty or more rival bidders. Fair Rent and Fixity of Tenure are under such conditions much better assured to the large farmer than they are to the small man, and the former is therefore less interested than the latter in the possibility of State intervention. The Act of 1907, as has already been shown, provides for a Fair Rent, so far as newly-created holdings are concerned. The land- owner is obliged to let to the local authority, and to take a rent estimated by a "fair" valuation, not unduly driven up by the presence of a crowd of small agriculturists outbidding each other, but based in the first place upon the amount hitherto received for the area. He cannot demand an increased rent at pleasure when the first lease has run out, and so exploit the increased profit which the tenant has perhaps just begun to draw. For the Council is at liberty to conclude a new lease and again to fix the rent according to the same "fair" considerations as before. Fixity of Tenure is also guaranteed by the Act to some extent, since the Council, acting as landlord, may only give notice to quit to any tenant on grounds defined in the Acts of 1892 and 1907, or because he does not fulfil his obligations. The occupier can no longer be turned out of his holding, at least within the duration of the Council's lease, for such reasons as the improvement of the shooting or hunting of the estate, or some personal antipathy towards him on the part of the landlord ; on the ground of his political opinions, or of his system of cultivation ; or simply from the landlord's sudden desire to add the acres in question to his home farm. Even if conditions arise which allow the landowner to reclaim his land, the tenant has a right to compensation (see Schedule I, Pt II (5)). As regards Free Sale, it has been pointed out above that the small holder's claim to compensation can be much more easily and effectively made when the local authority intervenes between him and the landlord ; and this is considerable progress in the direction indicated by that phrase. Every landlord, however, is perpetually faced, under this Act, 142 Large and Small Holdings by the possibility that he may lose, over some part of his property, what have hitherto been the most important of his functions as a landowner. The rent to be paid for the land may be authoritatively prescribed for him, if the County Council should see fit to hire it by compulsion. The duration of the lease will also be dictated to him. Improvements made by the occupier without his consent must, if they increase the value of the land, be paid for by him at the conclusion of the lease. Very little is left of his rights of property, and it is quite comprehensible that a Party which represented his interests should have objected more strongly to such an attack on those rights than to the proposal to compel the sale of a few hundred acres at a reasonable price. The powers of the County Councils were still further extended by the Act of 1907 to enable them to support co-operative associa- tions which may aim at the creation of small holdings or at assisting their occupiers by means of credit, co-operative purchase or co- operative marketing of goods. The Councils may even call such Associations into existence and use them as their " agents " (section 39 (i — 4)). This provision opens the way to a combination of official action with voluntary effort which may prove of the greatest benefit. Co-operative purchase of land and the foundation of a sort of colony of small holders by co-operative means (not, of course, cultivation on a co-operative basis) may have excellent results. This has been proved by the various Small Holdings Associations, especially those of Norfolk and Lincolnshire, which have done remarkably well in the creation of prosperous little farms. In fact, the results of such co-operative undertakings have tended to produce an opinion that the official attempts were often fore-doomed to failure precisely because a County Council cannot proceed in the same eminently sensible manner as a private association. The division of the land, the erection of buildings, the fencing, drainage work and so forth are all certainly effected more cheaply by private effort than by a local authority. From this point of view the well-known agricultural author, Mr Edwin A. Pratt, is right in commending the co-operative creation of small holdings as against State action1. But before the co-operative association can act it must be able to acquire the necessary land, and that under conditions such as to make the forma- tion of small holdings possible. How dark the outlook was in that direction was shown by the evidence given to the Committee of 1905-6 by Mr Winfrey, himself the President of two such Associa- 1 E. A. Pratt, The Transition in Agriculture, 1906, pp. 260 f. Legislative Action 143 tions. Mr Pratt indeed argues that "a trustworthy society or combination " would offer to the landlord the necessary security for his purchase-money or his annual rent. But the division of the land is necessarily an experiment even for an association, and the landlord might well remain long in doubt as to its power to pay, however convinced he might be of its goodwill. But where an Association is backed by a County Council, so that the fear of compulsory hiring is before the landlord's eyes, and the Council becomes security for the Association for a certain amount, as by law it may, the way to a satisfactory agreement becomes much easier. The powers given by the Act of 1907 enable the official body to work in with the voluntary association. The latter retains its economic advantages, but it is strengthened, where it feels the need, by the authoritative backing of the Council. It is always to be remembered that the authority of the State only comes into play, in this matter of the creation of small holdings, for the purpose of removing hindrances from the path of a socially and economically beneficial development. Where small holdings develop spontaneously, or where voluntary associations find it easy to call them into being, there the Council remains out of action. But where difficulties stand in the way of the satisfaction of a real demand for such holdings, there is the sphere of the Acts of 1892 and 1907. And here again the authority attempts in the first place to bring about a voluntary agreement. Only if such an agreement cannot be arrived at does the provision for compulsion come into force. The greater the hindrances, the stronger are the means at the disposal of the authorities for their abolition. The essential provisions of the Act of 1907 have now been out- lined ; and it should have become evident why it is that the Act may justly be entitled an agrarian reform. It aims at so transforming the conditions of landownership that they may no longer be a hindrance to the development of small holdings in English agriculture, suited as that development is to the modern circumstances of the agricultural market. The miscarriage of the Act of 1892 in no way proved that the small holdings movement has no future. On the contrary, the strong demand for such holdings, as brought before the County Councils, and the manifold successes of grouped small holdings where such were created, showed that the economic conditions, so far as they depend on the unit of holding, are favourable to the develop- ment. But what the results of the Act did prove was that the existing conditions of landownership were so unfavourable as to counteract the favourable economic conditions ; and that some more 144 Large and Small Holdings radical and incisive action on the part of the authorities was necessary if any solution of the question of the unit of holding were to contribute to agrarian reform generally. It was necessary in the first place that there should be some central authority in a position to take over the powers of recalcitrant local authorities, and so to ensure a better execution of the law than had so far obtained. But in the second place the introduction of a really new principle was required. It had become evident that mere permission to the County Councils to acquire land was quite ineffective in cases where land monopoly and the resisting-power of the great landowners prevented an agreement. Power of expropria- tion had become absolutely inevitable. Even this important reform did not suffice to solve the difficulties arising as between the problem of the ownership of land and the problem of the unit of holding. Compulsory purchase could indeed make the acquisition of the necessary soil possible. But the market price of land in England being so much above its capitalised agricultural value, and this price being still further enhanced by the cost of expropriation, it remained doubtful whether the land so acquired could be made to pay in the form of small properties. Compulsory purchase could not abolish the fact that it was often necessary to pay for qualities of the land which were of value to a wealthy landowner, but not to a small cultivator. Hence the third and most important change in the law, the change which more than either of the others expressed the demand for a change in existing conditions as a measure of social reform ; in view of the difficulties created by land prices and landownership as they stood, the hope of creating a class which should in the main be a class of peasant proprietors was given up, and compulsory hiring was instituted, with the intention of bringing the creation of small tenant-farmers into the foreground. If under modern conditions the large farm had remained the most profitable unit of holding, no one would have attempted to limit the right of landowners to the free disposal of their land. For, as Mr G. C. Brodrick remarked as early as 1881, "it is a trite saying that large farms always go with large properties1." The law of compulsory hiring expresses the fact that the form of landownership created by historical conditions and now existing in England does not correspond to the needs of modern agriculture so far as the unit of holding is concerned : that is to say, that large properties and small holdings cannot go "hand in hand." The recent legislation 1 Brodrick, op. cit. p. 393. Legislative Action 145 endeavours to modify the harmful conflict of interests thus set up. It leaves to the landlord his property in the land, but it obliges him, where the need arises, to let it in accordance with the modern economic pressure for small holdings. The English landlord may in future still value his land for the sake of the sport it provides, the social consideration it ensures him, or the political opportunities it offers him, and may pay as high a price as he pleases for these qualities of land regarded as a luxury. But its value for these purposes can no longer prevent the increase of small holdings, for if the landlord refuses to meet an existing demand for them, the State will force him to use his land as is most desirable from the economic and socio-political points of view. If in this way a divided owner- ship of land arises in certain cases, it is because the increasing tendency to regard the land in the first place as a luxury and only in the second place as an instrument of production has made such a divided exercise of the rights of property necessary. Such considerations are however rather of theoretical than of practical importance. For the compulsory clauses only come into operation where no voluntary agreement can be arrived at ; that is to say, in case of necessity. This is a point which has often been over- looked by the opponents of the measure. The Quarterly Review, for instance, writes : — " So far as owners of land and other property are concerned, almost any bold measure of socialism would be less harassing and oppressive than the annual crop of semi-socialistic measures which has been the characteristic feature of recent legisla- tion, particularly that of the present government1." And the writer concludes his annihilating criticism of the new legislation by suggest- ing that the only really effective method, if any change is to be brought about at all, is to buy out the landowners of the country according to the receipt of Henry George. He thus overlooks the fundamental difference between the existing legislation and any such sweeping measure ; the difference which makes the Act of 1907 one of reform and not of revolution. The Act does not undertake any general transformation of the conditions of landownership. In the first place, it only interferes where the creation of small holdings is economically justified ; and in the second place it only interferes where the conditions of landownership prevent such a development on non-economic grounds. In contradistinction to the plans of communistic land reformers it refuses to limit in general the rights of property in land ; it will only limit them just at the point where 1 Quarterly Review, 1907, p. 222 n. L. 10 146 Large and Small Holdings they oppose a development which is desirable from the purely economic point of view. The Liberal Party has thus succeeded on the one hand in keeping itself clear from the fantastic proposals for a general nationalisation of the land1, and on the other hand, unfettered by the antiquated dogmas of an older Liberalism, in opening up the way of progress. The second point is specially worthy of notice. What would the pre- decessors of the modern Liberals — Cobden, Hume, Bright or Roebuck — have said to State attacks upon landed property as contained in the Act of 1907? They would probably have felt inclined to leave for other countries, where sufficient virtue still remained to stigmatise such proposals as preposterous Socialism, totally unworthy of men who claimed the name of Liberal. But modern English Liberals are not terrified by the idea of property as conceived by their forbears. They aim at forming a programme which shall correspond to the needs of their time, independently of the history of the dogmas of political economy. " Liberty," writes Mr Asquith, " is a term which grows by what it feeds on, and acquires in each generation a new and larger content2." Hence they have created a programme of agrarian reform based not simply on the abolition of entails or on the avoidance of protective tariffs, but aiming at a positive, constructive end, namely at the creation of a new class of small cultivators. Thanks to the English Parliamentary system, under which no Party can afford to be without a programme on any question of living economic importance, the Conservative Party, as has been seen above, has also adopted proposals for the State creation of small holdings. The two Parties are divided only on the question of the means to be used for the purpose. Moreover it is interesting to notice that the original pioneers of the movement, Mr Joseph Chamberlain and Mr Jesse Collings, who were in the eighties regarded as mere dreamers* when they contemplated the possibility of compulsory purchase, are now able to advocate the same measure with a peaceful conscience from the bosom of the Conservative Party. For compulsory purchase is now a Conservative method, as contrasted with the compulsory hiring advocated by modern Radical reformers. So adaptable are political opinions in a country where political parties on the whole compete, not to represent the special interests of some particular class, but to serve the general interests 1 As represented by the Land Restoration League and Land Nationalisation Society. 9 Samuel, op. cit. p. ix. 8 Cp. Sir E. Colebrooke, Small Holdings, 2nd ed., Edinburgh, 1886, p. 17. Legislative Action 147 of the national economy, regarding its claims as more pressing than those of special interests or party dogma. (b} The working of the Act of 1907. Such being the provisions, and such the aims, of the Act of 1907, the question naturally arises as to the degree in which it has so far justified its existence. It is however obviously difficult to give a satisfactory answer, in view of the short time for which the Act has as yet been in operation, viz. only since January I, 1908. In the two years 1908 and 1909, 60,889 acres were acquired by the County Councils for the purposes of the Act, of which 34,234 were purchased and 26,655 were taken on lease1. As compared with the results of earlier legislation these figures appear very satisfactory and full of promise for the future. It is true that up to the end of the year 1909 the whole of the area had not yet been apportioned to small cultivators. The actual process of home colonisation takes place slowly, and in many cases the figures given above represent contracts, either of sale or lease, which did not come into force till after 1909. But it is certainly a remarkable fact that by December 31, 1909, 2793 small holdings had been created by the County Councils, representing an area of 36,845 acres. Only 28 acres had been acquired by their occupiers by way of purchase2. The provision for expropriation contained in the new Act has also been used to a considerable extent. Altogether 169 Compulsory Orders have been laid before the Board of Agriculture in the first two years of the Act's existence ; 59 of these have been " for the com- pulsory purchase of 7676 acres," and 1 10 " for the compulsory hiring of 4670 acres." By the end of 1909, 79 of these Orders had received the sanction of the Board. A still more important point is that in the case of compulsory hiring the Board, through its employment of an arbitrator or valuer, has obtained land at a considerably lower price than had originally been asked for it. In one case land for which the vendor had demanded £28,967 was compulsorily acquired for £23,485. In another, about £48 rent had been demanded for a farm of some 19 acres, and this was reduced by the valuer to £34S. On the other hand the County Council concerned had in almost all such cases to pay more than it had originally offered. As a rule the f 1 Annual Report on Small Holdings, Pt. i, 1910 (Cd. 5180), p. 5. 2 Ibid., p. 6. s Ibid., pp. 7-8. 10 — 2 148 Large and Small Holdings price set by the arbitrator practically split the difference between the price or rent asked by the vendor and the price or rent offered by the Council. The state of affairs does not look quite so satisfactory when the number of applications for holdings is compared with the number actually created. In 1909 the County Councils received 3157 appli- cations for land which altogether amounted to 54,572 acres. But of these applications only 1770 were approved, for an area of 26,611 acres1. Conclusions by no means favourable to the practicability of the Act have often been drawn from these facts, and more especially from particular cases where applications have been refused. In many circles and among many politicians the view predominates that the administration of the Act is not being adequately carried out, and that its success is in this way being imperilled. A not unimportant movement has in the course of 1909 taken shape in the Land Club League2, an organisation whose aim is avowedly to improve and accelerate the working of the Small Holdings Act. At a meeting of the League on March 4, 1909, complaints were heard from various quarters to the effect that County Councils had refused many perfectly justifiable applications, and had shown altogether too much tender- ness for the interests of the landlords and holders of sporting rights, while the Board of Agriculture had often remained inactive, so that the law, excellent in itself, could only succeed in meeting a fraction of the real demand3. The Board of Agriculture seems itself to be conscious that some such view is widely held : for its latest Report (1910) contains the following significant remark : — " We think that in the great majority (sic) of cases there is no justification whatever for the view that hostility or apathy exists on the part of those responsible for the administration of the Act4." In spite of this denial, the impression remains that the Small Holdings Commissioners are attempting to defend themselves against complaints of which they are very clearly conscious. It would certainly be unjust to complain of the administrators of the Act simply because they have refused certain applications for land. Undoubtedly it is in many cases difficult, and even impossible, at once to meet the demand for small holdings. Undoubtedly too in 1 Annual Report on Small Holdings, Pt. I, 1910, p. 24. 1 See The Land Club Movement, a descriptive pamphlet issued by the Land Club League, 2nd ed. 1910. 8 See the League's periodical, Our Land and Land Club News, Feb. 1910, pp. 9-1 r. 4 Annual Report on Small Holdings, 1910, p. 18. Legislative Action 149 other cases either technical agricultural conditions in the particular district, or the personal qualifications (or absence of qualification) of the applicants, make it undesirable to provide such holdings, if not altogether, at any rate immediately. But on the other hand hindrances certainly do occur in numerous instances which are not based on such material or economic circumstances. Since the interests of the landlords, land-agents and large farmers are strongly represented on the County Councils and the Small Holdings Committees appointed by them, while the small men get very little representation, it is unquestionably the case that the dislike of those classes of the community for small holdings may prove a very serious difficulty in the way of the effective administration of the Small Holdings Act. On the other hand the past two years have clearly shown that where a few active and energetic men take up the question, there small holdings rapidly increase. Cambridgeshire, for instance, stands before all other counties for the number of its newly created holdings : a result which is admittedly due to the energy and talent for organisation of the Chairman of the Small Holdings and Allotments Committee, Mr E. O. Fordham1, who has entirely devoted himself to the service of the movement. But in general it would certainly seem desirable that the Board of Agriculture should exercise its powers where the County Council refuses to act, and that if these powers are not yet sufficient they should be further enlarged. The Act of 1907 would undoubtedly be in evil case if the central authority should prove negligent. The two first Commissioners, Mr E. J. Cheney and Mr M. T. Baines, have worked hard to increase the number of small holdings. Their reply to the pessimism of certain sceptics or opponents is most encouraging : — " It is commonly supposed," they say, "that small holdings can only succeed in certain localities, where the soil is particularly good and where there are special facilities for the profitable marketing of the produce. But as a matter of fact the conditions which make for success are much more widespread than might be at first imagined8." But on the other hand it is a matter of common knowledge that the Board of Agriculture contains very influential men who are naturally prejudiced in favour of the landlords and the large farmers of the older agriculture, and are not merely sceptical about, but actually opposed to, the new movement. These men do not change when the 1 Report of a Conference as to the Administration of the Small Holdings Act, 1908 pp. 6 ff. and 31-33. 2 Annual Report on Small Holdings, 1910, p. 18. 150 Large and Small Holdings Government changes ; and although the permanent Civil Service of England is not supposed to represent any particular political party, it is unavoidable that its private opinions should to some extent influence its administrative functions, so that the line of action adopted receives a distinct political bias where personal initiative is required, or where personal influence comes into question. A Minister cannot get away from the influence of his politically opposed subordinates, unless he is a man of quite unusual energy and capacity. Here again, therefore, political considerations make themselves felt in regard to a purely economic question. And unfortunately it seems as if the Liberal reform had rendered the political friction in the small holdings movement more acute than before. For the Conservative Party continues to hold fast by the ideal of the peasant proprietor1, and defends its ideal nominally on economic grounds, whereas in reality it is determined by the dislike of landlords for compulsory hiring, the " three Fs," and limitations upon the rights of property. The consequence is that the small holdings question is increasingly side-tracked out of its proper lines of economic discussion, to become the plaything of political programmes. "The small holdings problem," as Mrs Wilkins writes2, "has been dragged into the arena of party politics ; the battle is raging round the questions of ownership and tenancy." However the struggle may end, its mere existence must be fatal to the chances of any well-considered policy of home colonisation. State action, however, as has already been indicated, has by no means been the only method by which the multiplication of small holdings has been attempted. Along with State action has gone a great deal of effort in the same direction set in motion by private initiative. All such effort has depended more or less upon the co-operative principle. Agricultural co-operative associations were to be called into existence for the purpose of acquiring and cutting up properties. Of these, the associations formed by Mr R. Winfrey are perhaps the best examples. Mr Winfrey first founded a Small Holdings Syndicate3 in the neighbourhood of Spalding in Lincoln- 1 A Small Ownership Committee has been formed under the presidency of Sir Gilbert Parker, M.P., to which very prominent Conservatives belong, its object being to further the creation of small properties. As the best defence of this point of view the reader should consult Sir Gilbert Parker's book, The Land for the People, with a preface by the Rt. Hon. A. J. Balfour, M.P., 1909. 2 Mrs Wilkins (Miss L. Jebb), The Small Holdings Controversy, 1909. Mrs Wilkins here expounds clearly and instructively England's need of a class of tenant farmers. 3 Report of the Co-operative Alliance Congress, 1902, pp. 343, 3+5, 349. Legislative Action 151 shire, where he was able to rent holdings from Lord Carrington, who is strongly in favour of the modern revolution in methods of holding. By 1904 the syndicate held 650 acres let to 200 tenants. Mr Winfrey came to the conclusion that considering the price of land and the general conditions of landownership the small man did best to rent and not to buy his holding1. He only bought land even for the associations when he found it impossible to obtain it on lease, as in the case of his second foundation, the Norfolk Small Holdings Association, which held 339 acres in 1904. Another similar under- taking, in which Sir James Blyth and Mr J. H. Whitley took part, was the Small Holdings Association of Newdigate in Surrey. This association devoted itself to the creation of small properties, the area to be from 3 to 25 acres. The purchaser had to pay down ten per cent, of the price, and then paid half-yearly instalments of capital and interest, the rate of interest being five per cent, and the total capital being paid off in ten to fifteen years2. Such co-operative procedure has considerable advantages over either self-help or State effort in the matter of the creation of peasant properties of larger or smaller extent. An area of two or three hundred acres can be bought cheaper than a single holding: and indeed many landlords who may be willing to sell a good-sized slice of their property would not consent to alienate a farm here and another there. As against the local authority, these private associations have the advantage of being able to carry out the necessary preliminary works, such as the erection of buildings, fencing, drainage and so forth, at a much cheaper rate than a public body3. It is a further advantage when these associations take from the beginning a genuinely co-operative form, and bind their members to common buying and marketing of goods. Nevertheless it seems doubtful whether the fundamental difficulty of the cost of land can be overcome even by co-operative purchase and other co-operative or quasi-co-operative methods. According to the prospectus of the Surrey Association, their land, though said to be bought well below the market-price, cost £20 — £30 an acre. Whether small men, unable to save a great deal, and not having any profitable by-employment, can pay such a price seems very problematic. It appears likely that such associations will mainly benefit small shop-keepers, industrial 1 Cp. also the views of another keen supporter of small farming, W. L. Charleton, in Small Holdings and Co-operation, Newark, 1901, p. 10. 2 Other similar associations were the Aylestone Co-operative Allotments Society Ltd. in Leicestershire, and the Land Association Ltd. in Nottinghamshire, the latter being pro- nouncedly co-operative in character. 3 Bear, A Study etc., p. 86. 152 Large and Small Holdings workers, little capitalists and so forth ; that is to say, the class which is prepared to pay something for the non-economic advantages of landed property. The experience of Lord Wantage's Land Company, for example, was that this class was the first to make use of such opportunities1, rather than the small holders and agricultural labourers for whom they were intended. The Act of 1907, however, strongly favoured the formation of Agricultural Co-operative Associations (cp. s. 9); and accordingly new results are to be recorded since the date of its coming into force. In 1909 fifteen Small Holdings Societies or similar associations of a co-operative character hired land, amounting to 1893 acres, under the Act. And the Small Holdings Commissioners wrote in their most recent Report that " the experience of the last two years has strengthened our conviction that the method of establishing [such holdings] with the best prospect of success is to acquire an area of land and to let it to a properly constituted Co-operative Association under section 9 of the Act1." It is necessary nevertheless to beware of ascribing such an extension of small holdings as has yet been achieved either to voluntary reform- ing zeal or to the Small Holdings Acts. Neither has been in any sense a main cause of the progress shown by the statistics. Even so far as they have been effective, it has not been because their aim was socially justified, but because it was economically possible. For more than a century similar efforts had been made without any success worth mentioning. That legislation and association for these ends was even possible was due to economic conditions. Up to 1880 the champions of the small holdings system had the economic tendency of the time against them ; the more recent agricultural developments have been very much in their favour. Since then also dates the small but perceptible result achieved. If the branches of agriculture which form the proper domain of the small farmer were still unprofitable, all attempts artificially to create small holdings would be as unsuccessful as ever. Indeed, the importance of market conditions and choice of employment to the small holder are generally recognized. Thus the Surrey Association carefully chose for its holdings grass-land of the first quality, as being specially suited for the purposes of both stock-farmers and fruit-growers : i.e. it 1 Shaw Lefevre, op. cit. pp. 254 ff. 2 Annual Report on Small Holdings, 1910, p. 14. Permission to let land to such an Association has to be given by the Board of Agriculture, which has laid down rules on the subject, widely distributed by the Agricultural Organisation Society. Legislative Action 153 recognized that the profitableness of those branches of agriculture was a fundamental condition of the success of small holdings. Many theorists deduce from these facts the proposition that all such socio- political action is quite unnecessary ; that the economic tendency will make its own way. Mr Kebbel, for instance, says : — " The number of small farms seems to me to have declined with the extension of arable land. May it not be that their revival will be a natural consequence of the restoration of this land to grass? I think this is worth waiting for; and that any legislation would be premature till the probable extent of the change which is already in progress can be first calculated1.". But it would be, to say the least, one-sided to regard these State and voluntary efforts from so fatalistic a standpoint : and this because the question of the unit of holding is only in part an economic question. If the course of its development were simply dependent on economic or capitalist conditions, it would be quite correct to say with Mr Kebbel that the increasing profitableness of pasture-farming and market- gardening would bring about a rapid change in the size of farms without any interference by the State or by social reformers. But though the fundamental economic conditions are favourable to the rapid extension of the small holdings system, non-economic forces are making in the contrary direction: and against these the conscious attempt to revive the system on the ground of its social advantages may be a very effective weapon. 1 Kebbel, op. cit. p. 160. CHAPTER IX THE RESPECTIVE ECONOMIC ADVANTAGES OF THE LARGE AND SMALL HOLDING INTRODUCTORY IN the preceding chapters the recent evolution of the system of agricultural holdings in England has been sketched. It was seen to be characterised by a diminution in the number of large and very large farms and an increase of small and medium-sized and also of allotment holdings. This tendency to diminish the area of the unit of holding has been shown to be due to the changes in the conditions of sale and production since 1879, the decreasing profitableness of corn-growing and the increasing profitableness of stock-feeding, dairying, fruit and vegetable culture, etc. These latter branches of production prove to belong, on the whole, to the domain of the small farmer, who on the other hand only undertakes corn-growing as an altogether secondary matter : so that the change in the relative profitableness of the various branches of production necessarily favoured the small as opposed to the large holding. It remains to consider why the various units of holding are particularly fitted for certain branches of production : why one kind of product belongs to the domain of large farming, and another to the domain of small farming or petite culture. The answer to these questions will throw much light on the connection between the current conditions under which production and marketing are carried on in any country and the system of agricultural holdings adopted. The problem is, what are the economic laws which govern the relation between a particular branch of agriculture and a particular type of holding? Thus stated, it appears as a compromise between the two theories on the question of the unit of holding which were defended by earlier students of agricultural economy. One set defended the large farm and another the small farm : some were convinced that the former was the one Economics of the Size of Farms 155 desirable type of holding ; others, with equal conviction, declared for the latter. The actual historical development in England has proved both sides to be mistaken ; the champions of the small farm were contradicted by the facts of 1760 to 1880, their opponents by more recent developments. Their common error was in discussing the question of holdings apart from any reference to the uses which they might serve. They aimed at discovering perfectly general advantages and disadvantages of this or that type of farm, and so determining the type which at all times and for all purposes was absolutely the best. It is true that some such general advantages and disadvantages do exist, irrespective of the particular branch of agriculture pursued. But history has proved that the economic superiority of one type over another is mainly dependent on their respective relative ad- vantages in regard of certain kinds of product The large farm, for instance, flourished when the price of corn was high and failed to maintain itself when the price fell. Moreover many of the particular superiorities adduced as absolutely valid were really only valid in regard of some special branch of production. The large farmers of the eighteenth century were undoubtedly better educated than the peasant holders : but whereas this was held to be a general advantage of the large farm system, it was really only of importance where arable farming made demands upon the intelligence of the agriculturist in order that the new scientific and technical discoveries might be applied. The lack of such intelligence was of no great importance on, say, a small dairy farm, which depended mainly on the intensive personal activity of the occupier. Again, the great advantage which the large arable farmer had in the purchase and use of labour-saving machinery was indeed significant so far as concerned the competition between large and small arable farmers, but not for any comparison between large arable farms and, say, small pasture farms, where such machinery was either not needed at all, or at any rate was not a conspicuous item in determining the profitableness of the holding. If these mistakes of the old — and indeed of many recent1 — students of the question are to be avoided, the advantages and disadvantages of the various units of holding must be considered separately in regard of the various branches of agriculture. By this method the danger of ascribing general importance to relative advantages will be avoided. Such a discussion must of course be limited to the chief points in each case, all secondary matters being dismissed as briefly as possible. 1 See my review of Dr Eduard David's book, Sozialismus und Landwirtschaft, Vol. I, Berlin, 1903, in Deutschland, November 1903, pp. 191 ff. 156 Large and Small Holdings When the good and bad qualities of the various types in regard of the various products, or the special qualities of each unit of holding, have been established, it will remain to consider what general qualities may be ascribed to each ; qualities, that is to say, which belong to a particular type of holding whatever use it may serve. The cost of buildings is always higher per given area under small farming than under large, for example, and this is a disadvantage of small holdings which has nothing to do with any question of the branch of production pursued : for the cost of buildings varies very little whether a farm is devoted to corn or to vegetables. The influence of these general advantages or disadvantages on the competition between the various units must therefore be estimated, as also their effect in weakening or strengthening any special qualities of a unit. These special qualities, however, will first be dealt with. A. IN RELATION TO THE VARIOUS BRANCHES OF AGRICULTURE. (a) Corn- Production. Small farms have proved profitable in recent times, but, as has been shown, they are still not as a rule devoted to corn-growing, which remains the prerogative of the large farm. Small farms which did grow corn felt the crisis severely, and their occupiers apparently suffered even more than the larger holders under the depression. The question is therefore as to the causes of the superiority of large farming in regard of corn-production. It will be remembered that Arthur Young laid much emphasis on the relative cost of ploughing on large and small farms, and the point seems still to be one of great importance. The expense of purchasing horses obviously falls very heavily on the small agriculturist. In addition, he is not as a rule in a position to make full use of these expensive animals when he has bought them. Mr C. S. Read stated that to give full employment to two horses an arable holding must cover at least 40 acres1. Small holders, if they keep horses, are consequently obliged as a rule to find some by-employment for them*. Often they send them to work on the holdings of other small farmers when they are not using them themselves. Others undertake carrying work in addition to their farm work, and so make use of their horses 1 Read, op. cit. p. 8. 2 See e.g. Small Holdings Report, 1889, qu. 2647-2648. Economics of the Size of Farms 157 in their spare time; or they may take passengers to and from market1, or into the neighbouring towns, covering by this by-employment what they lose through their incapacity to give full employment to their beasts. But such by-employments can only be undertaken by allotment holders, and not by the small farmer, whose holding will claim the whole time of himself and his family. And even allotment holders cannot be sure of fully compensating themselves in this way for the necessary expenditure on their horses. In districts where small holdings are common, for instance, there is no sufficient demand for this superfluous horse-power. In such cases the small agriculturist tries if possible not to keep a horse at all. He gets his ploughing done by some neighbouring farmer. A large farmer will often do this for him at cost-price. But naturally he has to wait until his neighbour has done his own work, with the result, very often, that his holding is ploughed in wet weather and sown at the wrong time2. A small farmer3 holding 40 acres told the present writer that he had at one time eight acres of arable, but had given this up, because the necessary horses cost too much in view of his rent. Small patches of arable could only pay, he said, if the farmer had other work for the horses on the roads. The case is altered, of course, when the horses are not required in the first place for plough-work, but for carrying the produce of the holding to market, perhaps daily, or several times a week. In such cases it will pay the farmer to keep one or two horses : ploughing will be a mere by-employment for them, their chief work being the carrying business. Thus in giving evidence on the small holders of Shropshire Mr W. H. Lander stated that they kept horses for the purpose of carrying poultry to market and of taking passengers, and also used them in the actual farm-work. "If he has to hire a horse to plough his ground of course that alters the question altogether, for if he has to pay for horse labour it would very soon take away all the profit4." On the other hand, as the area of the holding increases the relative number of horses required decreases. The small arable farmer holding 20 acres needs as many horses as one holding 40 acres, for, as has been seen, not till the latter area is reached can two horses find full employment. An arable farm of 80 acres, under ordinary circumstances, will not require more than four horses ; while one of 160 acres will only require six5. Statistics 1 E.g. Report of 1894, qu. 33,310. 2 Read, op. cit. p. 9. 3 Mr Ackland, of Long Bennington, near Newark, Notts. 4 Report of 1894, qu. 33,298 ff. 6 According to Mr Davis of Pensaxt and Mr Selby of Epworth (Lincolnshire). Mr Rider 158 Large and Small Holdings show this relative decrease of horses kept as the holding grows, though it must be remembered that the statistics showing the number of horses on the various units of holding refer to holdings of all kinds, pasture as well as arable : and also that the number of horses kept does not depend simply on the requirements of the plough, but on various other circumstances, especially in the case of small holdings. Taking the first point into consideration it is evident that the number of horses per 100 acres on small arable holdings must be much larger than would appear from the figures given below : for the holdings enumerated must include thousands of small pasture farms on which no horses at all were kept. But the second consideration mentioned makes in the other direction, since if all horses not kept for ploughing purposes were deducted there would be a great diminution of numbers, especially in the case of the smaller holdings. Only within these limits can the figures be used to show that arable farming on a small scale entails a greater relative expense for horses than on a large scale. The following table gives the percentage of arable land in the total area under consideration, as well as the number of horses kept per 100 acres. Class Percentage Horses kept of Holding of Arable land per 100 acres (1885) i — 5 acres 26*87 7'4 5—20 „ 2470 5-6 20—50 „ 33-31 5-3 50 — loo „ 42 '48 4-9 100—300 „ 47-92 4-3 300—500 „ 53-09 3-8 500 — looo „ 58-06 2'3 over looo „ 53'9o 2*6 Thus while the percentage of arable land increases in the larger holdings, the number of horses kept per acre decreases considerably. Even under the limitations indicated above, the result shows clearly that fewer horses are needed for large than for small arable holdings. It appears that while on holdings of I to 5 acres, about 29 horses are kept per 100 acres of arable, holdings of 5 to 25 acres have about 22, but holdings of over 1000 acres not more than 5. It is clear that the main proposition is established, though the difference would not be so extraordinarily great if it were possible to take the necessary limitations into calculation. Haggard also gives some instructive figures (in op. cit. Vol. II, pp. 190 f. ) as to the horses kept on 14 holdings in Epworth. According to these, holdings of 20, 25 and 30 acres keep two horses, while holdings of 50, 80 and even 100 acres only keep three. Economics of the Size of Farms 159 A second advantage possessed by the large over the small arable farmer is the cheaper use of labour-saving machinery. The steam- plough is a machine which is quite out of the question on a small holding, since a large area is absolutely necessary if it is to be used profitably. However, this is not a point of much importance, nor has it had much effect in the competition between large and small farms in recent times. The steam-plough has not fulfilled the hopes which were once set upon it1. It is now only used in England on holdings having very large cornfields : nothing is heard of that general use of it which was justifiably expected about 1870. The steam threshing-machine, on the contrary, has found much more extensive application. Middlemen keep such machines and hire them out to farmers who cannot afford to buy them or whom it would not pay to keep one for themselves. Not only allotment holders and small farmers take advantage of this system, but also the occupiers of middle-sized holdings. Large farmers, on the other hand, almost always have their own. It pays them to buy a threshing- machine because they can almost always use the engine for other purposes. A certain Kentish farmer1, for instance, has bought a crushing-mill for the purpose of making the steam-engine belonging to his threshing-machine useful. This steam-driven machine produces all the food-stuffs which he needs for his numerous cattle ; and as he uses his own raw material he is sure of having them of the best quality and unadulterated. Such a machine costs .£25. A straw-chopper is often driven by the same engine which is used for the threshing-machine, and sometimes actually at the same time3. The small farmer cannot put an engine to use in such ways, because he has not the capital to buy the various machines. Even the occupier of a medium-sized holding cannot afford to do so, as a general rule. And as the corn to be threshed by men of these classes is not sufficient to make it worth while to buy an engine for this alone, they find it much better to hire their threshing-machines as required. But by this method they pay more for threshing than their larger neighbours, who can make full use of a machine and soon pay off its cost. Also it must be re- membered that the transport of the threshing-machine from farm to 1 See e.g. W. J. Maiden, Recent Changes in Farm Practices, in Journal R. A. S., 1896, p. 39 : — "Steam cultivation, which twenty years ago bade fair to become more general, has receded in popularity, and the advantage which was expected to result from it has not been realised." * Mr Douglas, of Fish Hall Farm, Tonbridge. 3 Stephens' Book of the Farm, 4th ed., Edinburgh, 1891, Vol. l, pp. 449, 454. 160 Large and Small Holdings farm is expensive, and has to be paid for by the hirer. Farmers who hire their machines, too, are tied down to certain days, whereas the farmer who has his own has it at his disposal at any day or hour. In consequence of these difficulties small holders are often obliged to resort to hand threshing-machines. The latter thresh about 10 — 25 bushels an hour, whereas the steam-engine threshes 48 — 65 bushels. Nor is the case of other machines used in arable farming more favourable to the small man. For example, almost every farmer has a drilling machine. It costs £,2% to £30, or on a farm of 30 acres about ^i an acre. The same machine can do the work needed on a farm of 300 to 400 acres, when the cost will be only about is. 6d. per acre1. Then there are winnowing machines, corn fans, straw elevators, sowing machines, the very widely used reaping machines and the reaper and binder. All these are found almost exclusively on the large arable farms. The small farmer cannot afford to buy them, and these particular machines are not to be hired. Unless he can borrow them from a large farmer he has to do without them ; that is to say to carry on his farm without the aid of the modern improvements in technique. A few words will suffice as to the qualities of the various types of holding in relation to the cultivation of green and root crops, a matter which only comes into consideration here in so far as such crops play an important part on farms devoted to corn-growing. Where they are only grown for the purpose of feeding the stock on the particular farm, their production is not, of course, to be regarded as a branch of agriculture pursued for its own sake. Here the question is as to their production concomitantly with corn-production and for the market, that is to say, generally speaking, simply as an item in the system of rotation adopted on large arable farms. Large farming appears to have the same advantages in the case of these crops as in corn- growing. All that has been said as to the lower cost of ploughing naturally applies to them also. Nor is there any essential difference between the two kinds of crops as regards the application of machinery. Turnips, in particular, require a great deal of machinery if cultivated scientifically. And even if the small farmer can get the use of the machines, he still cannot obtain the same results as the large farmer. To obtain a good turnip-crop it is necessary, among other things, that the very complicated process of sowing and manuring should be carried 1 Small Holdings Jteport, 1889, qu. 7492 (evidence of the Secretary of the Farmer's Club, Mr Druce). Economics of the Size of Farms 161 through as far as possible without interruption. Various stages inter- vene between the opening of the furrows by the drill-plough and the final sowing of the seed. On a large farm with plenty of horses and a well-developed division of labour they can be made to follow at once one upon another, or even carried on side by side : and this is a great technical advantage1. Again, for all these crops plentiful and well-applied manure is important : and here again the large farmer, comparatively strong in capital, has the advantage. He can use a manure-spreading machine, which lays the manure evenly and without waste over the fields. Such a machine costs .£18 or ^19*, and it would therefore be too expensive for the small holder. Another disadvantage which hampers the small man considerably, both in regard of corn-growing and of green crops, is the unfavourable position in which he stands when buying either seed or chemical manures. The large farmer gets cheaper rates and better goods because he buys on a large scale. The small farmer often has to put up with poor and adulterated goods. The many qualities in which the large arable farm is superior to the small are thus evident. The small farmer, on his side, has hardly anything to set against them so long as he remains an arable farmer. No doubt, working himself with his family, he gets his labour cheaper than his rival, as even the occupier of a medium-sized holding does very often. But the saving so made is far from compensating for the large farmer's command of labour-saving machinery. And what is even more important, the labour of the occupier and his family has here no peculiar qualitative value. Corn-growing depends on relatively simple mechanical processes, and makes no special demands on the interest and industry of the labourer. It allows of, and even demands, more than any other branch of agriculture, division of labour as between the manager and the operative, the head and the hand. It can be admirably carried out by wage-labour, supervised and directed by the occupier or by a farm-bailiff. So far as the large farmer does take a personal share in the work, it is, as pointed out above, not for the sake of economising labour, but because it puts him in a better position to direct the work of his employees. In corn-growing the qualitative properties of the work of the owner play a very small part ; and thus the small farmer has nothing to compensate for the various advantages of large scale production in this particular branch of agriculture. 1 Stephens, op. cit. Vol. II, p. 348. 2 See the catalogue of the firm of Sergeant, Northampton. L. II 1 62 Large and Small Holdings (£) Vegetable and Fruit-growing. In English agriculture the most important vegetable and fruit crops are as follows : of vegetables, cabbage, cauliflowers, brussels sprouts, carrots, celery, beans, peas, tomatoes, cucumbers and potatoes ; of fruits, (i) orchard fruits, apples, pears, plums, apricots and cherries, and (2) garden fruits, strawberries, raspberries, gooseberries and currants. As to the cost of cultivation, the first noticeable point is that the great difficulty of the small corn-growing farmer, namely the dispro- portionate expense of the necessary horses, disappears. In fruit and vegetable culture the horses employed are not as a rule needed simply for ploughing, but chiefly for the purpose of carrying the goods to market. The produce must be carried into the town or village at least on market days. Fruit and vegetables are not sold in great quantities and at a certain time, but as they ripen from day to day : and a horse and cart are therefore necessary even on such holdings as send their goods by rail to the larger centres, unless they lie in the closest possible proximity to the station. Accordingly the small holder has employment for a horse in his own business, for other purposes than the actual cultivation of the soil : and in fact on the smallest holdings the main use of the horse is for transport purposes. This is especially the case where a little grower has customers in the neighbourhood, and takes fresh fruit and vegetables to them almost daily. Where a small holding is in the immediate neighbourhood of the market or of a railway station no horse may be needed for trans- port. But in such cases the use of a horse for cultivating the soil is also often unnecessary. In these favourably situated holdings, if not larger than i — 5 acres, the plough can be replaced by the spade. Spade-culture is suitable almost solely for fruit and vegetable-growing. The relative cheapness of the product makes it economically impossible in the case of corn. It would not pay to cultivate a corn-field of four or five acres with the spade, even though the gross produce might be increased. But the higher price obtainable for fruit and vegetables might make the use of the spade worth while. On the other hand spade-labour is much too expensive to be used on larger areas, even when devoted to these crops. The excellent results it gives are there- fore a distinct prerogative of the smallest holdings. The little holder, helped by his family and working longer and harder than a hired Economics of the Size of Farms 163 labourer, finds spade-culture much less expensive than would the occupier of a larger holding. To the latter the cost is prohibitive1. The question of machinery does not enter into this sphere except so far as potato-growing, a subject to be considered below, is concerned : so that the large farmer gains nothing from his capacity for acquiring expensive machines. In regard of these crops human labour is the essential matter, and more particularly those qualities of human labour which can least be replaced by mechanical means. Fruit and vegetable crops thrive best where every individual plant, bush, tree or fruit has received the greatest amount of individual care and attention. Standardised treatment, such as is possible in the case of corn, is out of the question here. The constant watchfulness of the labourer and a loving attention to every detail are what is needed1. In other words, a different kind of labour is required for this branch of agriculture, namely work of a qualitative intensity. Ploughing, harrowing, drilling, sowing, reaping and so on are processes which allow of more or less mechanical activity on the part of the worker. But in setting plants, cutting cabbages, choosing out ripe fruit or properly grown vegetables, picking and packing soft fruit, etc., care and intelligence are indispens- able. The treatment of fruit-trees and the successful cultivation of garden-fruit also make great demands on the attention of the worker. But the less mechanical work there is to be done, the less suitable is hired labour. " Fruit-growing and market-gardening would not be so prosperous were it not for the attention given to the crops by the excellent and hardworking cultivators of Evesham and district," says the Journal of the Royal Agricultural Society3. Personal interest is the only force strong enough to call out the care, attention and pains- taking exactness required for petit culture. It is not enough for this personal interest to be directed to the mere organisation of work which is to be mechanically carried out by other men's labour, as in corn-growing ; it must be concentrated on the actual labour itself. The greater the share of the work taken by the occupier and his family, the better will the conditions be fulfilled which are essential to success. This explains why this branch of agriculture is proper to small holdings ; the personal labour of the occupier can naturally only be applied over a limited area. Accordingly it is found to be the general rule in England, that the larger farmers, who undertake corn-growing and pasture-farming, 1 R. Scott Burn, Systematic Small Farming, 1886, pp. 159 f. 2 James Long, A Handbook etc., pp. 129, 131. 3 Journal R. A. S., 1908, p. 104. II- 164 Large and Small Holdings produce scarcely any fruit or vegetables for the market. On the other hand there are holdings, and whole districts of such holdings, entirely devoted either to fruit or vegetables or to both together ; and in these districts some large holdings will be found. The present writer saw a market-garden of 600 acres in Lincolnshire, almost entirely under vegetable crops. A hundred acres were devoted to celery1. Mr Bear mentions two brothers in Kent who hold 1000 acres almost exclusively devoted to strawberries and currants2. But market- gardens on such a scale are exceptional. They often have extensive forcing houses, the use of which has very much increased of late years in England. Such houses naturally require a considerable expenditure of capital, and are therefore out of the reach of the small man. But this is not the chief reason for the existence of these very large fruit or vegetable farms alongside of the smaller gardens. Mr Bear, who has given much attention to the development of hot-house culture, considers that its importance in the competition between large and small holdings is less than that of the advantage in marketing possessed by the large holder3. Two methods of sale must be dis- tinguished. The gardener may himself sell his produce in his own neighbourhood ; or he may sell it through a middleman in some market either near or distant, either selling outright to the trader or giving him some sort of commission on the sale. The latter method is generally in use when the goods are sent by rail to a market at some distance : and in this case the small holder is at a great disadvantage as compared with his larger competitor. In the first place the railway tariff4 is almost always so arranged that the relative cost of transport diminishes with the amount to be carried. Consequently the man who can send the greatest quantity has pro- portionately least to pay. In the second place, the large grower, selling wholesale, can as a rule make much better bargains with the trader than the small holder can5. In the large grower the middle- man meets a man accustomed to business transactions ; in the small 1 Mr Blaides' holding, Epworth, Lincolnshire. 1 W E. Bear, in Journal R. A. S., Vol. IX, Part I (1899), pp. 14 f. * Ibid., Vol. x, Part n (1900), p. 44. * See the figures given by Sir Francis Channing, op. cit. pp. 268 ff. They show that the so-called "reduced tariffs" always begin at z. certain minimum quantity only, and that this minimum is often set very high. Consequently those who have less to send than this minimum are at a great disadvantage. Cp. also Bear, A Study etc., p. 20. 5 Eyre, op. cit. p. 6 : — " I have heard very various reports as to the prices obtained, which, on the whole, go to prove that the man who deals in small quantities always gets less than the man who can send large supplies." Economics of the Size of Farms 165 man he finds an inexperienced agriculturist, with whom he can have his own way. These circumstances have probably contributed to the custom by which the large growers almost always produce for the great central markets, whereas the small holder — i.e. in this case the man with 3 to 8 acres — only supplies the neighbouring district, unless he happens to be close to some great centre. But this state of things has not so far proved injurious to the small holders. Often they get from their private customers, or selling retail in their own shop or "stand," better prices than the large growers selling wholesale to the dealers1. Indeed, the price of fruit and vegetables often rules higher in the neighbourhood of the producing districts than it does in the great markets, where it is often rapidly depressed by the quantity of goods sent in2. In the year 1903, for instance, the great markets, such as London, were glutted with celery, while in the neighbour- hood where it is chiefly produced, namely the Isle of Axholme, there was a positive dearth of it3. Such occasions naturally profit the small holder who does not work for the central markets, whereas the large holder suffers under the depressed prices there. The very small gardeners, holding ^ to 2 acres, and keeping neither cart nor horse, sell in their own immediate neighbourhoods, as do the allotment holders, who have often produce for sale even from a holding of £th of an acre only, if their family does not happen to be large4. They sell either to large farmers, or to artisans, or small shopkeepers, inn-keepers, etc. Such a market is ruled more by custom than by any other factor, and the sellers can generally dispose of their wares to their satisfaction. Thus the inability of the small and very small holders to reach the central markets, and their limitation to the local market, is certainly a disadvantage to them arising from the competition of the large growers. It is desirable that all markets should be open to all goods. But still this disadvantage has not so far seriously injured the small market-gardeners. The markets which are open to 1 Bear, A Study etc,, p. 57: — "In the course of my investigations I met with many examples of the advantage to small fruit-growers of selling their own produce, either to consumers or to stall-keepers, shop-keepers, or hawkers. In most of the great towns of the midland and the northern counties there are large fruit and vegetable markets, in which growers have stalls, attended by their wives or other members of their families, who sell at retail prices. In one instance a small grower said he had realised nj. a bushel for his apples, while a large one, who sold at wholesale prices, had averaged only 4^." 2 Long, op. cit. p. 133. 3 So the present writer was informed by Mr Blaides of Epworth. 4 Onslow, op. cit. pp. 49 f. 1 66 Large and Small Holdings them often suit them better than those which the large grower supplies. Methods by which they might command all markets will be discussed below. It is often said that the large, capitalist grower can manure his land better, and therefore obtain a larger gross product, than the small man. The premise may be correct, but the conclusion is not so. For the small holders can make up for the disadvantage of a some- what less intensive manuring by the use of spade-labour, an advantage, as already pointed out, peculiar to the small grower of fruit and vegetables. Thus neither the advantages arising from a larger disposable capital, such as the provision of forcing-houses or of better manuring, nor those in regard of marketing, can produce a decided superiority of large over small holdings in the growing of fruit and vegetables. The large holdings lack as a rule the essential condition for the profitable pursuit of this branch of agriculture, namely the intensive application of labour. The small fruit-growers in the Evesham and similar districts are said to be at work by three in the morning in the height of the season. Of the small holders in Devonshire a correspondent of Mr Read wrote: — "The farmer himself with his eldest boys works harder, and many more hours, than a paid labourer does nowadays1." Such industry results from the keen interest of the men in their own holdings, and the returns they look for not simply in money, but in the establishment of their independence. The work they do is not only quantitatively more than, but qualita- tively different from, anything which the large holder can obtain by investment of capital or hiring additional labour : and this qualitative intensity is precisely what is above all demanded by market-gardening. Hence the small holder has always one great advantage over the large grower*. Potato-growing, as already mentioned, is an exception ; but it is an exception which proves the rule. Where potatoes are grown for the market, and are the first or even the second object of the grower, the large holding appears to be the most suitable unit Like corn- growing, potato-growing depends on simple processes which can be carried out mechanically. The importance of individual attention is 1 Read, op. cit. p. «. 2 Mr C. Whitehead, Agricultural Adviser to the Board of Agriculture, also came to the conclusion that fruit-growing "is specially suited to the cultivators of small holdings," owing, as he says, to the fact that " fruit, as well as vegetable production, is an engrossing occupation, requiring immediate and personal attention, which a small cultivator would delight to give." See Long, op. cit. pp. 135, 131. Economics of the Size of Farms 167 small as compared with the importance of an abundant application of capital. Machinery, which in regard of other vegetables is practically useless, comes into play again here, especially in potato-harvest. The potato-digger, with three horses, can work three or four acres a day where the field is large enough, and the necessary assistants are at hand to gather the potatoes, and " on most large holdings the potato-digger is therefore called into use," says The Book of the Farm1. On a small holding not more than two to two and a half acres can be dug in a day, according to the same authority. Other machines too, effecting an enormous saving of labour, are only applicable on large holdings. On one such in Hertfordshire2, with 100 acres under potatoes, the present writer saw in use a potato- setting machine which did in one day, with one man, work that would otherwise have taken three men four days, and did it much more regularly. The same farmer had also a potato-sifter which sifted ten tons a day, employing four men, whereas the old sieve, attended by two men, disposed of one ton a day only. In potato-growing, therefore, the quantitative intensity of the labour of the small holder and his family can hardly compensate for the absence of machinery : the qualitative intensity of such labour is not needed for the mechanical processes to be performed. Potatoes also require a great amount of chemical and natural manure, which the large farmer is in a better position to obtain than the small. Spade- work, which compensates for this disadvantage in the case of other vegetables, is not so profitable in potato-culture, owing to the rela- tively low value of the product. The allotment holder, growing for his own use or to sell in very small quantities, may make use of spade-labour. But the holder of 3, 4 or 5 acres, desirous of making potatoes his chief crop, will hardly find spade-work pay. If he has to use the plough, the difficulty of finding other employment for his horses arises. Potatoes are not marketed in small quantities, but are harvested all at one time and sold wholesale. Unless the small holder grows other vegetables, or fruit, in addition to his potatoes, he will hardly be able to make full use of his beasts. His case is the same as that of the small corn-grower. When market-gardening is said to offer special advantages to the small holder, therefore, potato-growing, unless in combination with other crops, must be excepted. Where potato-growing by itself, and 1 Stephens, op. cit. Vol. in, p. 118. 3 Mr Muir's farm, Burslon Manor, Park Street, Herts. 1 68 Large and Small Holdings for the market, is concerned, large and medium holdings are superior to the small farm. But this superiority is obviously due to the fact that the technique of potato-growing is altogether different from that which makes the other branches of vegetable-growing a suitable sphere for the small holding and the small agriculturist. (c) Stock-farming. Stock-farming is a title which includes very various branches of agriculture. Breeding, rearing young cattle, fattening, dairying, sheep- farming, pig-keeping, poultry-keeping and the breeding of pedigree or herd-book stock may all be included under this head, although there are very great differences between them as regarded from the point of view of the holding economically suited to each. (i) Cattle-breeding. In the first place the breeding and fattening of cattle and sheep may be considered : and here it is necessary to draw a distinction between farms which are mainly arable, and grow their own feeding-stuffs and straw, and those which are mainly pasture, and buy what other natural or artificial foodstuffs, etc. they may need. As has been seen above, until the abolition of the corn-laws stock- farming was quite subordinate to corn-growing as an object of English agriculture. Corn and the three-field system were characteristic of the average farm. The rotation of crops did not become general until the rise of meat-prices after 1846, when it served both to make corn- growing more profitable, and to enable the farmer to keep a much larger number of cattle. Between 1850 and 1880 corn-growing and stock-farming were combined, in such a way that on arable farms corn-growing did indeed keep the first place, but nevertheless the production of meat was regarded as of nearly equal importance. In more recent times it has come to be the chief object. The corn, where any is grown at all, is often simply grown for the benefit of the cattle, and not as an independent branch of production. On many arable farms of 1 50 — 300 acres it is only grown to provide winter food and straw, the farmer preferring to produce these for himself. On smaller holdings this is naturally still more markedly the case1. But arable land being proportionately more expensive on small holdings 1 W. J. Maiden, Recent Changes in Farm Practices, in Journal R. A. S., 1896, pp. 31 f. : — " Farmers have consumed more of their own produce on the farm, when circumstances have permitted. There is a decided advantage in thus consuming home- grown grain, as the in and out profits to the middleman, where grain is sold and cake is purchased, are saved." Economics of the Size of Farms 1 69 than on large, it is evident that so far as regards stock-farming on arable farms the large farmer has a considerable advantage over the small. He ploughs more cheaply, and can afford to use labour-saving machinery, and so gets his straw and winter fodder at less cost. He feeds his stock, therefore, more cheaply than the small holder. This is true of sheep-feeding as well as of cattle-farming. Where the farm does not include great sheep-walks or large areas of pasture, sheep-feeding can only properly be carried on by means of turnip and clover fields to be fed off by the flock : and this, as already explained, the large farmer can arrange more cheaply than the small. As regards root- crops which are not fed off on the field itself, as e.g. mangolds, the small farmer has indeed the advantage of harvesting them by means of cheaper labour : but this does not compensate for his loss at the time of ploughing. These considerations do not apply where sheep- breeding is conducted on pasture-farms. But here too the large farmer has the advantage. He can take the so-called " sheep-walks " — wide stretches of poor grass-land, often mountainous. To succeed on these, a man must have large flocks of sheep, which the small farmer has not the capital to obtain. Cut into small areas such farms would never pay1. The cost of the necessary fencing alone would be too heavy as compared with the value of the land. Therefore the use of such pastures, which are often excellent for the purpose, remains a prerogative of the large farmer2. As regards cattle-breeding on arable farms, the large farmer has other advantages besides those already mentioned. A small holder can often grow only part of the foodstuffs necessary, and is therefore obliged to buy. The large farmer, on the contrary, often buys only if he can on the one hand get what he wants at a low price, and on the other sell his corn dear. In Westmorland, for instance, I was told3 that farmers fed their oats to their own beasts, or sold them, according as the price of maize and oilcake was high or low. So that the large farmer is less dependent on variations in the price of foodstuffs than the small. Again, the large farmer can obtain the expensive artificial foods at a relatively low price, while the small farmer, as a rule, finds them altogether too costly4. 1 This is admitted even by enthusiastic supporters of the small holding system. Cp. J. L. Green, Allotments and Small Holdings, 1896, p. 89 : — " It would be absurd to cut up a large hill sheep farm, for instance, which is practically fit for nothing else but sheep feeding and breeding." Also Sir M. Hicks Beach in the Report of 1894, qu. 6058. 3 Walker, Small Farming, in Journal of the Bath etc. Society, 1902, p. 85. * By Lord Brougham's agent on his Eamont Bridge estate (Westmorland). 4 Small Holdings Report, 1889, qu. 7481 (Mr Druce). 170 Large and Small Holdings When pasture-farming is in question, the large farmer has still great advantages as regards the purchase of foodstuffs, which, whether natural or artificial, are very necessary on such farms. And here again he has the use of machinery, as e.g. grass-cutting and hay- making machines, which the small man cannot generally afford. Even if a small farmer does make up his mind to provide himself with them (for allotment holders, even of the larger type, it is of course out of the question) he has to pay at a higher rate for a machine of smaller capacity 1. Kelsey's Patent Chaff Cutter and Sifter, for instance, cost in 1904 : — To treat per hour Price 12 cwts. ^37 16 „ £43 20 „ £52. roj. 24 „ •" ^58 3° i, ^62 So that the farmer who bought the most expensive machine did not pay nearly double what the cheapest cost, whereas his machine, though only about 67 per cent, dearer, was of 1 50 per cent, higher capacity. The large farmer, therefore, saves both time and labour through being in a position to buy and make full use of a better machine than his small rival can do. Here again he has an advantage in pasture-farming over the small holder. The invention of hay-making machinery has been particularly important to the large farmer. Without it he would be at a consider- able disadvantage in this part of his business. The small farmer, in consequence of the more intensive labour (here quantitatively intensive) which he applies, can get through his hay-making much more quickly than the large farmer employing day-labour. Conse- quently he can often take advantage of favourable weather, and finish his harvest before bad weather sets in, while the large farmer takes longer about the work, and can seldom get in all his hay before a break in the weather occurs. To employ extra labour at a time when its price is high is a doubtful benefit. But the use of labour-saving machinery solves his difficulties. It does not indeed give him any superiority over the small holder in this sphere, but it does put him on the same level. In the result, the large pasture farmer, though the use of machinery helps him greatly, does not obtain by its means 1 See the catalogue of Kelsey and Co., Sheffield, p. 13. Economics of the Size of Farms 1 7 1 such a decided advantage over the small farmer as the large arable farmer does in his branch of farming. The use of machinery is among the points which make the large farm distinctly superior to the small for arable purposes. For pasture-farming it can only lessen the disadvantage at which the large farmer stands, especially in hay- harvest. Small farming has one specific advantage which is of the greatest importance in stock-farming, and even outweighs all the advantages which have been mentioned on the side of the large farmer. These advantages have all been concerned with processes only indirectly affecting the ultimate object in view, namely the beasts themselves. The actual work among the cattle has not yet been discussed. This is however the most important part of the whole business ; and it is just here that the small holder has an advantage so great as to make him master of the situation in many cases. In no other agri- cultural employment is so much individual attention and personal interest, that is to say such qualitative intensity of labour, needful. Careless or even rough handling of the animals may do very serious harm. Cows in calf or at the period of calving, young calves, sick or weakly beasts, all need most careful attention. So does the cleaning of the sheds and stalls, and many other matters essential to good cattle-farming. To all these things the small holder attends personally. He, with his small stock, is not obliged, like the owner of a great herd, to leave the handling of his beasts to the uninterested hands of the hired labourer, contenting himself with the supervision which naturally cannot be everywhere at once. The modern small holder is not behind his predecessor of the eighteenth century in his love for his beasts and the sacrifices he is willing to make for them. No detail escapes him, and the interest he has in them, and the pride with which he regards them, make him hesitate at no amount of labour which may improve their condition. A very able Gloucestershire landlord1 told the present writer that he thought small holdings best suited for calf-rearing; and that he let the hilly district which he owned in Shropshire to small farmers, as being appropriate for the purpose. In fact, in this sphere small farming seems to have a clear advantage over large, in consequence of the qualitatively intensive labour it demands. The same advantage applies to some extent to the fattening of cattle ; but it is not here of such pre-eminent importance, so that the small holding cannot be said to be absolutely superior to the large 1 Mr Granville E. Lloyd-Baker, of Hardwicke Court, Gloucester. 172 Large and Small Holdings for this purpose. The qualitative intensity of labour which it affords here rather serves to compensate for the advantages possessed by the large farmer in other directions : so that the two types of holding are practically on an equality. (2) Dairying. The great prerogative of the small holding, namely the personal work of the occupier and his family, is nowhere of such great importance as in that branch of stock-farming which plays a leading part in modern English agriculture, namely dairying. The small holder is at a great advantage in butter and cheese-making and in the sale of milk and cream, and very largely as a result of his superiority in the fundamental matter of milking. English agriculture is, as has been said, suffering under a very serious exodus from the land. The labourers who remain not only take advantage of their position to demand higher wages than heretofore, but they make more demands of all kinds ; they are more cultivated and more fastidious — results which from the point of view of civilisation in general are certainly desirable. Women's labour has very much diminished, and in many districts has ceased altogether1. The high wages earned by the men enable them to keep their wives (and also their children up to a certain age) at home, instead of sending them out as formerly to wage-labour for an outside employer. Moreover, under modern conditions the wives and daughters of agricultural labourers can often find very paying employment on their own allotments. But this impossibility of commanding women's labour is a serious difficulty for the employer, and more especially for the dairy-farmer. The larger farmers, whose families do not take part in the work of the farm, have been obliged to give up women milkers altogether : but they have not found that men are equally satisfactory in that capacity. This is a complaint which may be heard whenever a large farmer is encountered. The owner of a great steam dairy and of a large dairy-farm in Devonshire2 told the present writer that he gave his labourers idf. a week, with a free cottage and garden, on condition that they undertook to send their wives to do the milking daily. But few farmers are in a position to make such a stipulation. Most of them have to face the dislike of the women for wage-labour, and to put up with men as milkers. But even men are difficult to get. The younger labourers hate milking. They regard it as work to be despised. 1 Wilson Fox, Agricultural Wages, pp. 297 ff. 3 Mr Loram, the owner of the Cathedral Dairy at Exeter. Economics of t fie Size of Farms 173 They specially dislike all Sunday work, such as is of course required on a dairy-farm1. They want to have their Sundays free for enjoy- ment and for their best clothes, and not to be obliged to be at the cow-sheds at certain hours to milk or feed the cows. Nor is it the Sunday work only, but the kind of work involved in dairying, which makes them object to service on a dairy-farm. A Yorkshire labourer1 told me that both he and others had found that the younger men liked attending to horses, but not to cattle. The work was dirty, and in the evening the intolerable milking, with the accompanying dirty boots, came all over again. The older men, he said, had enjoyed looking after the cows, but the younger ones preferred any other kind of work. Such being the case, it is not wonderful that loud complaints are heard that the milking is done carelessly, lazily and dirtily. Such complaints come not only from large employers, but also from scientific students of English dairying methods8. " Cultivate the acquaintance of your cows, treat them kindly, and teach them to regard you as their best friend ; cows love kind treatment, and we may rest assured that it will pay," says Professor Thonger* with undoubted truth. But his words prove the necessity that the handling and care of the cows should be done by their owner. " Friendly " treatment is not to be expected from wage-labourers. If a farmer succeeds in finding men to do the hated milking, no doubt with suppressed ill-will, he has to be constantly on the watch lest their dislike of the work should find expression in some careless or unkind handling of the beasts, and so injure their health and the quality of their milk6. Nothing but the lively interest taken by the occupier and his family can produce the loving attention needed for the work. Agriculturists are to be found all over the country who have given up their dairies at the moment when it became impossible for members of their families themselves to do the work, whether because the wife became an invalid, or because the daughter married, or from whatever other cause. They preferred (and especially is this the case with the tenants of medium-sized farms) to turn to other branches of agriculture rather than to employ outside labour in the cow-sheds when home labour failed. But the large farmer is from the very beginning subject 1 Report on the Earnings of Agricultural Labourers, 1900, p. 54. a Mr William Johnson, High Farm, Brandsby, Yorkshire. 3 Sheldon, The Farm and the Dairy, p. 7 1 . Cp. also what is said on this point in the Estate Book, 1906, p. 278. 4 C. G. Freer Thonger, Some Essentials of Successful Dairying, in the Journal of the Bath etc. Society, 1903, p. Si. 5 Burn, op. cit. p. 320. 174 Large and Small Holdings to this serious difficulty if he wishes to take up dairy-farming. He must pay very high wages, and even then not obtain anything like the work which he admires in the small holder and his family, and which is the fundamental condition of success in this direction. Nor is it only in the actual milking that the qualitative intensity of the work of the small holder and his family is so essential. The same demand is made by the other work of the dairy, and especially by butter and cheese-making. Professor Sheldon points out that it is desirable in the interests of cleanliness that the maid who does the churning should also undertake the milking. But this is only possible, as he says, in a small dairy. On a larger farm the most she can do is to supervise the milking so as to see that it is done with as much regard to cleanliness as possible. It is above all things necessary that she should have a real sense of responsibility. " Herein lies the reason why farmers' wives are, as a rule, the best dairymaids — they feel the responsibility, and take a pride and an interest in their work," as the Professor puts it1. The same thing is seen in the case of cheese- making, and especially in the classic country of English cheese-making, namely Cheshire2. The best economic results are produced where no outside labour is employed, but the cheese is made by the farmer and his wife themselves. It is their personal interest in the work which leads the small holders positively to enjoy those details which the hired labourer regards as most irksome : and which produces effort of a qualitative intensity which wage-labour can never attain, but which is very necessary in the branches of production in question. The large holding has, it is true, some advantages over the small even in this sphere; such as slightly, though only slightly, to lessen the superiority of the latter. In the production of milk the large farmer has only one thing in his favour ; namely, a lower cost of transport. The small holder, owning from one to six cows, is at a great dis- advantage in regard of the marketing of his milk : so much so that it is often the large farmer only who supplies the great central markets. The case is the same as with the transport of fruit and vegetables. Most railway companies have tariffs for the transport of milk with rates diminishing as the quantity sent increases. Thus to send anything up to 12 gallons from Westmorland to certain districts costs is., while every further gallon costs id. only. Taking the average yield per cow per day as i^ gallons, the owner of six cows will have to pay is. per day for the transport of his milk. But the owner of twelve cows will 1 Sheldon, The Farm and the Dairy, p. Jt. 2 Brodrick, op. cit. p. 397. Economics of the Size of Farms 1 75 only have to pay is. ^d. This grading of the tariff results from the simple fact that the railway companies can transport large quantities at a relatively lower cost than small. The result is the same as with the market-gardeners. Part of the milk market is closed to the small holders. The same is true of butter for similar reasons. But, again as in the case of the market-gardens, this fact is often no real injury to the small holder. The small allotment holders, living in the village, often sell their milk to customers who themselves take their jugful home, so that no question of cost of transport arises. Or the producer may send his children out with the milk, and may find plenty of customers, at any rate in the summer, among visitors from the towns, excursionists, etc. These methods of sale do not concern the large farmer at all, as he never sells in such small quantities1. The butter of the allotment holder may be disposed of in similar ways. The larger allotment holders and the small holders proper have moreover a real advantage in this sphere, in the way in which they are able to sell to their own special customers in the neighbouring towns or villages. Even Mr Read, who is in general an advocate of large holdings, and fails to estimate the advantages possessed by the small holder at their real value, is obliged to admit that "in its distribution (i.e. the distribution of butter, etc) the wife of the small farmer, if a good market-woman, can generally make a considerable profit2." Naturally the small farmer often fails, through negligence or laziness, to make use of all the advantages which he has at his disposal. But some of them, at any rate, take the pains to carry their own butter into the town, and get from their customers throughout the year ^d., 4*/. or 5 /• * s cwts. £ cwts. £ cwts. £ 1886 1543 8141 1734 3871 1887 1513 8010 1836 4514 I 1888 1671 8913 1917 4546 352 734 1889 1927 10,244 1907 4490 339 704 1890 2027 10,598 ' 2144 4975 407 847 1891 2135 11,591 2041 4813 444 900 1892 2183 11,965 2232 5416 481 930 1893 2327 12,753 2077 5160 501 1009 1894 2574 I3.456 2266 5474 529 1079 1895 2825 14,245 2133 4675 545 1083 1896 3037 15.344 2244 4900 611 1170 1897 3217 15,916 2603 5885 756 1398 1898 3209 15,961 2339 4970 817 *435 1899 3389 17,213 2384 55<>3 824 H55 1900 3378 17,45° 2705 6837 987 1743 1905 4147 21,586 2442 6339 893 1584 1908 4210 24,080 2306 6684 920 1606 1909 4062 22,424 3390 6829 991 I73i The imports of other products of petite culture have also risen enormously of late years, as the table on the next page will show. Here also the figures are for thousands, the ciphers being omitted2. The imports of potatoes, onions and cherries also show a consider- able increase, as do those of vegetables ; but unfortunately the statistics for these last do not distinguish between the different kinds of vegetables, so that they are not available for our purposes. However, it is clear that the consumption of all these articles of food is enor- mously increasing year by year. The statistics also show that the value of the imports of butter, cheese, condensed milk, apples and eggs alone is about equal to the total value of wheat imported. In 1909 the value of those five articles of import was .£41,200,000, while 1 Cp. Agricultural Statistics for 1903, pp. 142 f., and ibid, for 1909, Part in, pp. 290-1. * Agricultural Statistics for 1903, pp. 152, 144, and ibid, for 1909, pp. 300, 292, 318. Conclusion 207 the average value of the wheat imported in 1908 and 1909 was £4 1, 700,000 \ Poultry Apples Pears Plums and Game ^Eggs Year , *• \ t A X f •*• \ Bshls. £ Bshls. £ Bshls. £ £ Thsnds. £ 1892 45 H 1353 637 296 412 199 583 1336 3794 1893 3459 843 915 347 777 331 578 1325 3875 1894 4968 1389 1310 411 777 302 480 1425 3786 1895 3292 960 407 1 66 401 1 66 605 1526 4003 1896 6176 1582 483 206 560 241 705 1589 4184 1897 4199 1187 1051 377 1043 497 730 1683 4356 i 1898 3458 1108 491 221 922 434 637 1730 4457 1899 3861 1186 57i 266 558 294 785 1940 5044 cwts. cwts. cwts. 1900 2128 1224 476 366 423 392 1010 2025 54o6 1905 3494 2065 417 407 480 524 999 2259 6812 1908 3376 2079 523 515 402 427 1052 2185 7183 1909 3129 2007 569 504 485 473 1028 2125 7233 The prophets of the nineties who held that the consumption of such produce would soon cease to expand were therefore obviously mistaken. The import figures prove that, on the contrary, the con- sumption of precisely those articles which are produced by small holders has vastly increased. There has also been an increase in the consumption of products which are not imported, as fresh milk, which has already been mentioned. Here again no figures are available, but every authority on English agriculture admits the growth of the consumption of milk as an undisputed fact. So Mr Anderson Graham wrote in April I9O32: — " Mr Hunter Pringle was of opinion when he wrote" (i.e. in his Report to the Commission of 1894) "that too many people were going into this (the dairy) branch of farming, and that it would be ruined by over-competition. Experience has not justified his forecast. The consumption of milk appears to grow, not only with the population, but per head." But the figures quoted above show that this undoubted increase in the consumption of articles proper to the small holder has by no means all inured to the benefit of the English agriculturist. The increase in the stock kept, in the area under fruit 1 Agricultural Statistics for 1909, p. 293. 2 In the Morning Post of April n, 1903, p. i. 208 Large and Small Holdings and vegetables, in the number of eggs sold and poultry kept, and so forth, do indeed show that English agriculture has taken some share in supplying the demand. But still a considerable part of the supply is provided by foreigners. This would appear to give force to the second objection mentioned above, namely, that the home production of articles of the kind in question is necessarily limited. It is claimed that the high import-figures for butter, eggs, fruit and the rest show that the conditions of agriculture in England are unfavourable to, and in part prohibitive of, the production of such articles. But the experience of recent years gives no uncertain answer to this suggestion. That one important branch of small farming, viz. stock-farming, has shown itself capable of extension has already been proved. When the agricultural crisis was at its worst, and the fall in the price of corn was making itself most severely felt, the absolute ruin of English agriculture was freely predicted. It was said that in Essex, Norfolk, Suffolk and other counties, soil and climate made it simply impossible to transform arable into pasture or in any way to develop stock-farming further than it was already carried. But the Scottish farmers acted while English agriculturists hesitated, and today even in Essex flourishing dairy-farms and market gardens are common. Where pasture has not been laid down, stock-farming is carried on by means of stall-feeding, a method which writers on the subject had long been pressing on English farmers1. A system of temporary pasture has also proved very successful where neither stall-feeding nor permanent pasture was suitable. Mr M. J. Sutton showed, as a result of his very thorough study of the question, how capable of extension this system of temporary pasture is*. There are thus no unconquerable difficulties in the way of the expansion of stock-farming and dairying. It is true that English farmers, like the agriculturists of every country, are conservative, and hold to their old traditions. They are often sadly lacking in the marvellous capacity for adaptation to circumstances shown by their Scottish brethren. To this conservatism is attributable among other things their great reluctance to adopt co-operative methods, necessary as these are in the interests of technical and 1 Lloyd Baker, Dairying in Denmark, Bath, 1896, p. n. See also Mr Graham in the Morning Post, loc. cit. 2 M. J. Sutton, Permanent and Temporary Pastures, 1888, pp. 4-5 : — "I quite admit that there are large tracts of land in this country which are unsuited for the formation of permanent pastures — But there is no farm land with which I am acquainted that will not profitably respond to the alternate system." Conclusion 209 economic progress. Persons acquainted with Danish methods of dairying declared in the nineties that England was twenty-five years behind Denmark in her butter-making1. It was not more favourable conditions of production, but co-operative organisation, and technical perfection in production and distribution, which gave Denmark and other countries their standing in the English markets. The question is whether England will adopt the methods of production and distribution demanded by modern conditions of international com- petition. The outlook in regard of other branches of production is much the same. The extension of fruit and vegetable-growing is also hindered by difficulties of a technical description. Thus, for example, Mr Morgan, the Secretary of the Fruit Growers League, told the Committee of 1889 that England had the same opportunities of successful apple and pear-growing as America ; perhaps better. English growers could in particular produce fruit of the best quality, for which high prices were obtainable. Thousands of tons of fruit which were yearly imported could be grown quite as well in England as abroad ; the English soil and climate were excellently suited for the purpose2. One authority wrote briefly3 : — " There are few farms that do not comprise one or more fields admirably adapted for the growth of such crops as table peas, French beans, celery, early cabbages, turnips, small fruit, herbs, etc. ; and still fewer farms that do not include an orchard capable of improvement or extension." An expert reported on the fruit-culture of Gloucestershire* that certain parts of the country " might easily have been converted into a veritable gold mine." " If such grand apples," he wrote, " can be grown on the brashy Cotswold soil by good cultivation, it shows what ought to be possible in the more favoured districts. Soils and positions are important factors in success, but the need for education is even more pronounced." Poultry-farming is another branch of agriculture equally capable of expansion. The enormous demand for fowls is by no means yet met by the supply6, so that such an expansion is very desirable. 1 Report of 1894,911. 4758. 2 Small Holdings Report, 1889, qu. 5806, 5809-13. * A. R. Cragg, Specialities in Farming, in the Journal of the Bath etc. Society, 1903, pp. 41 f. 4 Annual Report of the Technical Instruction Committee of the Gloucestershire County Council, July, 1902, p. 34. s Cp. Graham, The Revival etc., p. 126. L. I4 2io Large and Small Holdings But, as Mr Revv's report showed1, chicken-farming "depends not on local advantages, but on organisation and skill," and could therefore be developed in any district. The English agriculturist need thus be under no apprehension that the consumption of fruit, vegetables, dairy-produce, etc. will increase less rapidly than the production ; he need fear no over- production in this sphere. At present consumption is expanding much more rapidly than is the home production. But the reason is not that England lies under some technical difficulty or dis- ability in the supply of such produce. On the contrary, it is just as possible to increase the production of these articles in England as it is in the competing countries of Denmark, France, Belgium, etc. That these and other countries have at present to some extent driven the English agriculturist out of his home market is simply due to the better organisation which the foreigner brings to the production and distribution of his goods. England needs to adopt these co-operative methods of organisation with all possible speed. It is to be hoped that the efforts of the Agricultural Organisation Society in this direction may meet with the success they deserve. Nevertheless, in spite of all that English agriculturists have left undone in their work of turning the new market conditions to their own advantage, English agriculture has admittedly experienced a great revival of late years. The growing demand of the mass of the population for meat, fruit, vegetables, butter, cheese, milk, eggs, etc. secures its future in so far as it succeeds in adopting the best methods available, and in giving up unprofitable branches in favour of those now profitable. A condition of success equal in importance to that of the introduction of co-operation is, however, the maintenance of Free Trade. It is Free Trade which, by cheapening bread and meat, has raised the purchasing power of wages, and so increased the consuming power of the mass of the population, to the benefit of the agriculturist. But assuming that the economic development of England continues on the lines of the last quarter of a century, while agriculturists seize the advantages which they have by their own fault hitherto failed to seize, what will be in the future the problem of the unit of holding ? The future will be similar to the past. Small holdings will once again play the chief part. Where corn-growing, pedigree stock- 1 As summarised by Mr Charming, op. cit. p. 37. Cp. also the Estate Book, 1909, p. 154, under Chicken Rearing in Sussex: — "Why is this industry practically confined to this district ? There is not the least reason why it should be, as equally favourable conditions could no doubt be found elsewhere." Conclusion 2 1 1 breeding, or sheep-farming remain profitable, the large farm will survive, owing to the intensive application of capital which in these branches of agriculture gives it an absolute advantage over the small holding. But it will continue to make way for small holdings where the other branches of production are most profitable, and above all where the small holders succeed in organising themselves co-opera- tively. It will give way to the small holding, that is to say, where intensity of labour is of greater importance than intensive application of capital, as is the case in most forms of stock-farming and in fruit and vegetable culture. In the last resort it must always be the condition of the market which will determine the solution of the problem of the unit of holding. Non-economic tendencies may of course influence and limit the natural economic development : and here lies a great danger to the national economy1. For every hindrance to a necessary economic development is an injury to the mass of the people of the nation concerned. But for that very reason whatever social or political hindrances exist to the natural evolution of the unit of agricultural holding in England will not be permitted to continue. The people have the power, through their Parliamentary government, to get rid of conditions which are seen to be hurtful to their interests. The continued development of the small holdings system appears to be in every way advantageous to the national economy. It com- pensates for the decay of the large farm system in proportion as the extension of stock-farming and petite culture compensates for the unprofitableness of corn-crops. No doubt these branches of production make greater demands on the capacity of the individual agriculturist than corn-growing did. Small farming puts a greater strain on human faculties, and demands a greater output of personal energy, than was necessary in the days when the profits on corn were steady and the large farm system ruled. But just because its survival and development 1 A gloomy picture was painted of certain tendencies of this description by Mr W. Sea wen Blunt in the Nineteenth Century for 1906 (Vol. LIX), p. 964. He says: — "One thing however stands absolutely in the way, and must be changed before chicken fanning can become at all a general industry. I say it with regret, but without hesitation, chicken farming and fox-hunting cannot exist together ; and if we want to maintain the one we must not maintain the other. Chicken and egg farms fail principally in Sussex because to escape the depredations of foxes, the chickens cannot be let run freely in the fields and hedgerows, where to a large extent they should pick up their living. Shut up in wire enclosures the cost of feeding is too great. The fox is a wide night-roamer, and cannot be dealt with locally, as is the case with other vermin, by help of trap or gun or poison. Until therefore he ceases to be preserved by landowners it is useless to talk of our competing in Sussex witb the chicken industries of France, where the fox finds no quarter." 14—2 212 Large and Small Holdings make these demands it would seem to be in the highest degree favourable to the progress of English agriculture. From the point of view of social policy, on the other hand, a system of agriculture depending mainly on small holdings is undoubtedly the most satis- factory. Such a system prevents the rise of that opposition of class interests which is so marked a feature of the large farm system with its wage-labourers. The development of small holdings and allotment holdings lessens the great danger of capitalist agriculture, which is that the landless labourers drift to the towns, there to seek compensation for what they have lost upon the land. Nothing but small holdings can keep the people on the land so long as the industrial labour-market is open to them. Nevertheless, social reformers desirous of seeing the small holding system maintained and developed must admit, in view of the facts of English agricultural history, that it is the general economic conditions which at any given time and place determine the problem of the unit of holding. The small cultivator can only thrive when the articles which he can produce better and more cheaply than the large farmer can also be sold to better advantage than the characteristic produce of the large farm. The surest means of securing the existence of the small agriculturist is to raise the consuming-power of the mass of the population, by keeping their food, and more especially their bread and meat, free from taxation, and by reforming the conditions of town life in every possible way. For the better the condition of the labouring classes, the greater will be their demand for those articles in which the small holder finds his proper domain. Mr R. A. Yerburgh, M.P., who has already been mentioned as one of the great champions of agricultural co-operation, recently expressed in well-chosen words the tendency of the present conditions of agricultural life towards the maintenance of peace, both in social and in political matters. The reader who has followed the historical description given above will appreciate the truth of Mr Yerburgh's words, which are quoted here by his express permission, though they have not previously been printed. He says: — "The position of the farmer is now "entirely different to what it was when he depended upon the pro- " duction of the necessaries of life, corn and meat. Then, it is said, the " common toast at the farmers' ordinaries was ' To the next bloody " war ' ; the reason being that a war meant high prices for the farmer. " Now the situation is completely different The farmer with us is " chiefly interested in producing what we may call luxuries, such as " milk, cheese, eggs, poultry, fruit. The sale of these depends upon Conclusion 2 1 3 " the prosperity of the country. If war breaks out, our commerce and " industries suffer, and the wage-earners find their means of subsistence " threatened. The result is an immediate lessening of the demand for " luxuries, and a consequent diminution of prices for the farmer. Thus " the farmer now, in place of being interested in war, has a supreme "interest in peace; and as the small holders will be almost entirely "occupied with producing luxuries their interests will lie in the same "direction, and so they will be a powerful factor along with the " farmers in the preservation of peace." There is then harmony between the modern developments of English agriculture and agricultural holdings and the interests of the great mass of the population. Ricardo's dictum, that the interests of agriculture were irreconcilably opposed to those of the rest of the community, is no longer true. Since 1 846 England has refused to sacrifice the good of the whole to the interest of any class ; it has ceased to protect its corn-producers from foreign competition. To this policy it owes the rapid development of the small holding system, and the technical improvements in agricultural methods of the last five and twenty years. To this policy it is due that the inevitable crisis of 1880 onwards did not spell ruin, but led to the gradual re- organisation of the agriculture of the country. To this policy above all is due the harmony of interest between that re-organised agricul- ture and the needs of the great majority of the English people. APPENDIX I THE MODERN SMALL FARMER AND THE QUESTION OF HOME COLONISATION: A PROBLEM OF SOCIOLOGY PERHAPS German experience under the German settlement laws best shows what class of settlers is most suited to take up small holdings. They are men who were themselves in their earlier life little independent cultivators, or industrial workers living on the land, who have held a bit of land as a by-employment; or else peasants' sons, such as come from the west into Posen and West Prussia in order to be able to obtain land of their own. That is to say they are in any case men of peasant stock. "We see," writes Herr Belgard, "how e.g. the Westphalians and Hanoverians take the fine old peasant holdings of their homes for their model, and turn all their efforts to the creation of an equally stable property and equally excellent live-stock upon it1." It is the same class who when they emigrate become hard-working cultivators in foreign lands. Everywhere they carry with them a tradition and an ideal, in the memory of the conditions under which they grew up. How different are the conditions in England ! There is no peasantry to draw upon, unless in a few isolated districts such as the Isle of Axholme or a few places in Cumberland where yeomen of the old type are still to be found. The sons of small or medium farmers are early employed on their father's farm or on that of some neighbour; but when they grow up they begin to move away. They see nothing specially honourable in the fact that their father holds a farm, which, under the capitalist tenant-farmer system, may be here to-day and there to-morrow ; they do not see in it any hereditary obligation, or even anything which they desire to imitate. On the contrary, they are without traditions, and are only desirous of making their way into spheres which seem to them more satisfactory. Town life and industrial employment attract them. The father may have worked his way up from the position of a mere wage-earner to that of an independent farmer, and so after a long struggle have attained the goal of his highest hopes. But to the son that position seems a matter of course, and the desire for a higher social and economic standing awakes in him very early. 1 M. Belgard, Parzellierung und Innert ^Colonisation, Leipzig, 1907, pp. 340 f. Home Colonisation 215 It is therefore clear that the home colonisation of England cannot be brought about on the same basis as if the colonists could be drawn from an existing peasantry. If in Germany the settler has the sense that he is carrying on a tradition, and maintaining the social standard of his fore- fathers, in England quite other motives lead a man to take up a small holding. (1) England has an agricultural proletariat, a class of landless agri- cultural labourers, who may be brought out of their dependent position and established as small cultivators. This class has for over a century been produced as a necessary part of the large farm system ; while for some thirty years past the revival of small holdings has made it possible for its members to rise to an independent position. In their case there is therefore no question of the maintenance of a hereditary tradition ; on the contrary, when an agricultural labourer takes a small holding he climbs into a social position which is as a. matter of history altogether new to his class. Moreover, not only the social position, but also the whole economic position, is new to him. He will have worked all his life as a wage-earner on large or medium-sized farms, probably devoted to arable in the first place, worked in conjunction with stock-feeding based on large pastures and hay-fields : whereas on his small holding he will have to adopt branches of production which demand quite a different kind of labour, where machinery is at a discount, and the work must be done by hand in great detail and up to a very high standard of quality. Economic difficulties such as these can only be overcome by that peculiar zest for work produced by the hope of making so great a rise in the social scale. That this desire for independence does exist is proved by the fact that in the year 1909, for example, 25 per cent, of the applications for small holdings came from agricultural labourers. (2) The second category of possible colonists — and it is a very miscel- laneous one — consists of applicants who have not hitherto been in any way occupied in agriculture. They would, so far as their previous economic activity is concerned, be classed as town-dwellers, or at any rate as industrial workers ; but from their very various callings they desire to pass to the land. In this class, though not the most important part of it, are the village artisans and their congeners — butchers, bakers, grocers or small shopkeepers. To many of these, the Small Holdings Act is a means of obtaining land as a by-employment1. Their shop will remain the backbone of their economy. But others give up their industrial employment and devote themselves entirely to farming. Two examples of what men of this class have achieved are here appended, taken from the evidence given before the Committee of 1 Cp. Report of a Conference as to the Administration of the Small Holdings Acts, 1908, p. 35. 8 See Small Holdings Report, 1906. Minutes, qu. 2217. 216 Appendix I (a) George Batchelor. This man had been a village shoemaker with a rather small income. By energy and industry he saved enough to take a little holding, which he cultivated with great satisfaction and apparently with pecuniary success. He had in 1905 a banking account, and was adding to his land year by year. New buildings were erected on his farm at a cost of £180, so that the holding was brought into very good condition. (b) George Williams. This man had a newly-formed holding, the house and buildings having cost about ^340. He had been employed on the railway, but gave up his situation. He had planted his land with fruit trees ; and as he had a family growing up, his labour cost him very little. Another case, which was described to the Committee by the person in question himself1, was that of a quondam cobbler, who got tired of his work, and took an acre of orchard land. He ended by holding 30 acres, not as tenant, but as owner. A Wiltshire co-operative association, the Mere and District Small Holding Society, lets holdings of from one to 30 acres, chiefly for pasture-farms or market-gardens. Among its tenants are men who were formerly respectively a baker, an innkeeper, a decorator, a coach-maker, a road- mender, a groom, etc., and several hawkers2. In another county, Den- bighshire, a farm of 79 acres was cut up by the County Council. The largest holding, which covered 44 acres, was taken jointly by two brothers, who had formerly been miners in the neighbourhood. Their stock consisted of 14 cows, 19 pigs, two cart-horses and two ponies3. But one of the most remarkable examples of change from industrial employment to the independent position of small land-holders is offered by the history of Catshill in Worcestershire. A large number of the inhabitants of this village were nail-makers, and nail- making was apparently a "dying trade." Some of the ratepayers therefore applied to the County Council for land. The Council bought an estate of 147 acres, and formed holdings of 3^ to eleven or twelve acres. The nail- makers were thereupon transformed into market-gardeners. The fact that they were near the great market of Birmingham was of great service to them. They produced not only fruit and vegetables, but pigs and poultry, and needed no other employment. According to a report laid before the Committee of 1906 their position was most satisfactory4. All the settlers in the cases given above, although they did not come from agricultural occupations, had either lived on the land (as villagers, on the railway, in country house employment, etc.), or at any rate had not lost all connection with it. From these must be distinguished the type of settler who is a genuine town-dweller. A writer on the subject divides these into two groups5, namely, first, town workers who have country wives, or who 1 Small Holdings Report, 1906, Minutes, qu. 9012-9071. 2 Report of a Conference etc., p. 104. * Ibid., p. 89. 4 Small Holdings Report, 1906, Minutes, qu. 3901 ff., 3909, 4003 ff. 6 H. E. Moore, Our Heritage in the Land, 1906, p. 112. Home Colonisation 217 have had some experience of agricultural work, and who for the sake of the health of themselves or their family want to get into the country, even if they can only make a smaller income there. Secondly, town workers who see that in consequence of increasing age, or of the depression of their trade, they are likely to lose their employment in a few years, and drop to the position of casual labourers. There is no doubt that there is a considerable number of men of this latter type desirous of getting onto the land. The action of some of the labouring people of Leicester, most of them employed in the boot trade, is characteristic. A number of the factory workers put themselves in possession of allotments, having organised co-operatively for the purpose1 : and one of their objects, as reported by Mr E. A. Pratt2, was to use these allotments as a stage towards and an education for the taking of a small holding. And in fact the attempt to obtain allotments was soon followed by the formation in the same district of a co-operative association for the creation of small holdings3. Of town-dwellers of quite another type Mr Pratt writes4: — "Apart from the factory workers who have gained experience on allotments... there are men who, though intelligent, capable, and willing, are physically unfit for the stress and strain of life in great cities, especially when close confinement in an office or counting-house may be included therein. Others there are who, though considered 'too old' for the employment on which they have hitherto been engaged, still possess an amount of energy and vigour, the devotion of which to a healthy rural pursuit would... provide them with a fresh and more or less profitable employment.... Others, again, the sons of manufacturers, business men, or professional men, might well start in the country in some occupation which either appealed to their tastes more, or would suit the condition of their health better, than following in the footsteps of their fathers." Evidently the material available for home colonisation purposes from industrial employments or of the town type is of very various kinds ; it is in this respect very different from the material provided by the class first considered, which consisted mainly of agricultural labourers, and to some extent of farmers' or bailiffs' sons. It is certainly at first surprising to find that agricultural life does attract non-agricultural sections of the population ; the continued and well-grounded complaints of a rural exodus naturally seem to point in the other direction. Objections to any such movement were made before the Committee of 1906. Men well acquainted with the conditions declared that there was no sense in planting inexperienced townsmen on the 1 According to the Annual Report of the Agricultural Organisation Society for 1908, one of these co-operative societies, the Winchester and District Allotment Holders Association, rented 86 acres and had 660 members. 8 E. A. Pratt, The Transition in Agriculture, 1906, p. 268. 3 Small Holdings Report, 1906, Minutes, qu. 5059. 4 Pratt, op. cit. p. 306. 218 Appendix I land1. Mrs Wilkins (Miss L. Jebb) put the case more wisely when she said2: — "I do not much believe in bringing town people out of the towns to the country, but that is a very different thing from bringing back a man to his native district, where he has been in the farming or market-gardening line in his youth, and returns to it." But even this limited prejudice against townspeople hardly seems well founded so long as many examples can be found of successful small holders who have come from the towns and were of the towns. Mr Pratt, whose book has already been cited, and who is a well-known writer on agricultural subjects (he has explored the whole of rural England), takes a broader view of the matter. "The ordinary 'unemployed' of our large towns, and the ne'er-do-wells of urban life in general, are not the type of men who could be settled on the land straight off as small holders, whatever else might be done with them." But he enumerates a variety of "desirable town types," and adds: — "Starting with the assumption that the townsmen in question were alike intelligent, energetic, and determined to succeed, there ought to be no insuperable difficulty in the way of their acquiring, within a reasonable time, a sufficiency of knowledge... to be able to make, at least, a living" out of agriculture. "As a matter of fact, some of the greatest successes achieved in several of these minor industries of late years have been won by enterprising men from the towns3." The questions necessarily arise in this connection : What is the relation of these two most important classes of settlers, the agricultural labourers and the industrial workers, one to another? and, What is the comparative import- ance of the two groups ? The attraction of the land for non-agricultural sections of the population at the present day is by no means exclusively to be traced to a love for " mother earth," or a longing to go " back to the land " for its own sake. If this were the determining motive, its results must have made themselves evident long ago, whereas this return to the country is a phenomenon of quite recent date. The movement is certainly not less due to the fact that the re-organisation of English agriculture has created conditions which seem to be particularly well suited to men who have been brought up to trade or industry. The smaller branches of agricultural production, which have now become the very basis of English agriculture, make quite different demands on the farmer than would be made by a small holding devoted to corn supplemented by stock-feeding. The small farms of the eighteenth century also sold fruit, vegetables, eggs, poultry and so forth. But they sold them for the most part to customers in their own village or in the nearest market. The markets of to-day are as a rule far from the small holder himself, and the old personal relation of farmer and customer is gone. The farmer has 1 Small Holdings Report, 1906, Minutes, p. 474. 2 Ibid., qu. 7914. 8 Pratt, op. cit. pp. 306 ff. Home Colonisation 219 to produce for the trade, and to provide such articles as suit the wholesale dealers. Regular transmission of goods of a standard quality is, as has been seen above, essential. In the case of eggs, for instance, there are five or six recognised qualities, from the new-laid egg and the fresh egg to the cooking egg of the second or third degree. The goods must further be carefully packed in sawdust in specially prepared boxes. But these important points ' of grading and packing have more in common with the work to which a factory hand is accustomed than with that of the farmer or countryman of the old style. And the same is true in the matter of the sale of fruit. The business man, again, will find himself more at home in, say, negotiating the sale of the produce of a market-garden than will the old- fashioned agriculturist. The best profit on fruit and vegetables is to be obtained not by selling to the local dealer, but from some wholesale trader in a large town. A business connection with such a man has to be worked up. Mr Pratt says2 that some vegetable-growers get "js. to Ss. for their broccoli crates where others, less careful or capable in their choice of dealers, are beaten down as low as is. The first are, as Mr Pratt points out, "better business men." In this connection may be noticed the telephone question, which was discussed by an expert before the Committee of 1906. "A man who is producing goods of a perishable character, which might be perishing at the time he was about to telephone, would have exact information as to prices, and as to how the market stood, so that he could dispose of his produce instantly, whereas without the telephone he might have to wait so long that his goods would have perished altogether3." Here again it is evident that purely business qualities are of the first importance to the small holder under modern conditions. He must know the market, have good connections, and be quick to take advantage of favourable turns of price. Such demands, so far as small holders are concerned, are of quite modern origin. Again, not only upon the market- gardener, but also upon the small farmer proper, certain demands are made which involve more than a purely agricultural training. In the case of a dairy-farm, for instance, the English public, or at least its upper classes, demands milk which shall be pure and clean ; and the dealer has to assure himself that the dairy from which he obtains it is in a properly sanitary condition. To glance at some of the technical publications on the subject4 is to realise that the old-fashioned dairy has to evolve into something much more nearly resembling an industrial workshop. The proper cleansing of the cow-sheds, the sterilisation of pails and cans, the use of cooling-machines and modern methods of filtering, all demand something altogether different from the old-fashioned hand-labour 1 Cp. Leaflet No. i of the National Poultry Organisation Society, p. i. 2 Pratt, op. cit. p. 122. 3 Small Holdings Report, 1906, Minutes^ qu. 5620. 4 See Market Day Lectures, fpoj-6, pp. 33 ff. 220 Appendix I with bucket and dung-fork. Poultry-breeders using incubators, or growers of fruit and flowers under glass, are equally far removed from the old conditions. Worthing alone has 1220 forcing-houses, whose pipes laid end to end would cover more than 136 miles ; some of the growers there have artesian wells of their own ; some have small windmills or steam-machinery for pumping purposes1. Here again it is evident that we have a branch of modern agriculture demanding much technical knowledge and skill, and quali- ties not traditionally supposed to be found in the ordinary countryman. It may perhaps be suggested that where technical knowledge and a cultivated intelligence are essential there the large farmer has his proper sphere, whether or not the branch of production pursued be one otherwise belonging to the small holder. But the various demands made upon the cultivator in any case cannot be considered apart from one another. All authorities on English agriculture are agreed that for certain branches of production, as dairying, market-gardening and so forth, the fundamental condition is and remains the intensive personal labour of the occupier and his family; a kind of labour which can never be obtained from a hired labourer. For this reason the small holder has always an advantage in these branches of production over the large farmer. This advantage cannot be seriously endangered by the growing need for business qualities and technical skill. But these demands will have their effect on the total result which the small holder is in a position to obtain from his holding. The need for such qualities may be very much lessened if the small holders are co-operatively organised. Co-operation, in fact, may almost amount to a complete disburdening of the small holder in this particular. A cooling-station or steam-dairy takes over the mechanical part of the work of a modern dairy, and co-operative collecting depots relieve the farmer of the need for a business head. But co-operation is relatively speaking little developed in England, even though it is increasing; it is not everywhere applicable (e.g. where success depends on individual methods, or where the type of holding is very various, etc.); and it cannot take over all the functions which have been noticed as necessary on a modern small holding. Where therefore the large cultivator, in spite of his superior business capacity and technical knowledge, has not the advantage over the small holder, and where co-operative methods cannot relieve the small holder of the necessity of exercising such qualities, it is evident that the small holder who can bring these powers to his work will be the person best fitted to conduct a variety of branches of production, and will in fact have an extraordinary advantage in them. It becomes easy to understand why non-agricultural sections of the population are to-day being attracted into agriculture, and why they show such capacity for survival in the struggle for 1 Pratt, op. cit. pp. 90 f. Home Colonisation 221 existence. They possess already the necessary business qualities and technical capacity. Intelligent observers have not failed td recognise the nature of this development. Thus e.g. Mr Newsham writes of the small holdings of Hampshire: — "In most parts of the county there appears to be ample opportunity for the development of mixed holdings by men who have been brought up on the land and know the practical side of their business. The town-bred man must of necessity have an up-hill struggle, though his business capacity or training might stand him in good stead1." And Mr Pratt expresses the matter still more clearly : — " Industries, in fact, such as dairying, horticulture, floriculture, stock-raising, etc., as distinguished from the growing of corn, are occupations requiring technical knowledge, skill, business capacity, and unremitting personal attention on the part of those engaged therein — qualities and qualifications not necessarily possessed by even the average farmer of the old school, and still less by the average agricultural labourer of the passing generation, however efficient the latter may have been in the days when the work he had to do made less demands on his intelligence than upon his physical endurance2." Under some circumstances, therefore, the non-agricultural type of settler will prove more than equal to the man who has been on the land all his life. He will even be superior to him in certain branches of production, as in fruit and vegetable growing. But the agricultural labourer will be superior to the townsman when corn-growing and stock-farming are in question, because there technical capacity and business qualities have a smaller part to play, and his agricultural experience becomes a matter of great importance. In general it may be said that the non-agricultural settlers instinctively direct their attention to those branches in which they can best use their particular qualities. The place and kind of work they choose are regulated accordingly. Unlike the agricultural labourer, who is able to raise himself to an independent position, but then develops a tendency to comfortable methods, they are full of the desire "to get on." They retain a capitalistic character. They find in various branches of modern agriculture quite as good chances of profit-making as they could in trade or industry. This is noticed by almost every writer on the small holdings question. Mr F. Impey, of the Board of Agriculture, who has inspected many small holdings, has astonishing things to report on this part of the subject3. A land-agent who had over 1000 small holdings to administer told him that he knew dozens of men owning ;£ioo to ^500 who twelve or fifteen years earlier had been earning their 15*. a week. A man who had formerly been a groom and gardener stated that on his holding of 5^ acres he could save ^40 a year, 1 In the Journal of the Board of Agriculture, 1908-9, p. 93. * Pratt, op. cit. pp. 303 f. * F. Impey, Small Holdings in England, 1909, pp. 19-28. 222 Appendix I and in one year saved as much as £go. He had planted no less than 1400 fruit trees, and in one year sold 1000 head of poultry. In another case Mr Impey was astonished to find a man paying ^£5 rent for \ of an acre. But the occupier told him that the value of the strawberries sold off that bit of ground in the last year had been about ^58. It is no wonder that townsmen, hearing such stories, begin to think that there is " something to be made out of" even the land, if a man only goes about it in the right way. The material for home colonisation in England, then, is roughly of two classes. Men who have grown up under the influences of the town, men of commercial or industrial tendencies, stand side by side with men who have lived all their lives upon the land. There is room for both. Both, under the given conditions of production and distribution, that is to say in certain branches of production and under certain market conditions, may be fit instruments for the re-organisation of the unit of agricultural holding in England. There- fore what at first sight seems an extraneous element in modern agricultural society, viz. the quondam townsman or the man of city instincts, is not in fact to be regarded as an artificial product of reforming zeal. His appearance is a necessary result of the economic transition through which English agricul- ture has been passing in consequence of the ruin of what was once its special branch of production. And for this reason the lack of a peasant population will prove no fatal hindrance to the home colonisation of England. In many districts it is not peasantry of the old style who are appearing or who can appear. Agriculturists of quite other qualifications and outlook are in course of development ; agriculturists for whom a quite different social and economic organisation is growing up from that which the little farmers or yeomanry of the past could ever have possessed. APPENDIX II TABLE I Area of agricultural land under the various types of holding throughout the English counties. ( Arranged in four geographical districts from the merely alphabetical arrange- ment of the Return as to the Number and Size of Agricultural Holdings in 1895.) 224 Appendix. II i — 5 acre s 3 — 20 acre :s Total area Pasture- land Arable land Total area Pasture- land Arable land I. Bedford •S'jgC 1 2 CO 2126 11,847 402O 6918 Cambridge 5833 1078 •iSc; 23,706 6840 i6.oc6 Essex CC4C 7:62 J"33 108-1 20 216 1 1 2QI 802 C Hertford 2QC8 2401 CC7 80/10 67QO 21 sO Huntingdon 1808 1181 627 7847 4163 3284 Lincoln I7.OOI Q3Q8 8C03 82.!; 37 47.OQI 30,446 London 606 406 I IO IQ2C 1623 3O2 Middlesex 2173 1662 ci I 8020 6060 IQCI Norfolk 078O 4178 56ll 37,02 1 1 6.2 1 0 2I,7O2 Suffolk C76l 2?8t; 2776 I7.4o8 7234 IO 174 YorkE 5471 3235 2236 19,241 IO,8o6 8535 Total for District 60,830 3'»93S 28,895 240,607 120,355 120,252 II. Berks 2898 2381 CI7 II. I 17 883; 2322 Bucks 34QC 2582 QI3 12,763 061 ^ 3148 Hants 7080 C2C.3 2727 27,577 IO.O32 8q4q Kent 6643 4l6Q 2474 31 8?2 2O.Q 1 2 10,060 Leicester 4CQ3 42?6 3C7 26.7O2 24.i;26 2266 Northampton ... Notts 3974 C343 2704 4128 1270 I2IIJ 17,614 26.840 12,722 20. 14"? 4892 660 1; Oxford 3O2Q 1811 1218 I I.74O 7Qc6 3784 Rutland C72 476 06 32">O 2730 481 Surrey 3QIO 3141 778 i6,;78 I2,068 3610 Sussex 5811 4QIQ 802 2C.34C 21,018 4327 Warwick 5439 4434 IOO5 23,3°I 20,235 3066 Total for District III. Cornwall 53,696 10,337 40,234 742 C 13,462 2QI2 i 234,799 47,723 180,703 28,602 54,006 10,121 Devon 8348 6385 1067. 42,6lJ. 32,O74 IO,^4O Dorset 7J4O 24QO o^o 14,84.0 11,188 3661 Gloucester Hereford 8628 \\f\7 5825 3985 2803 477 27,235 10,440 20,610 16,360 6625 3089 Monmouth Salop 3021 Q83I 2673 8805 348 IO26 17,013 38,873 15,564 33,740 1449 CI24 Somerset IO,67I 8626 2O4C, 43,488 77%084 5 504 Wilts 4O8? 3186 1801 IO.C7O I4iIO^ 5377 Worcester 8175 4366 3809 25,155 18,953 6202 Total for District IV. Chester 71,000 lO.OSl 53,766 OO2O 18,174 IQC2 295,969 4^,O2^ 229,277 33.028 66,692 OO07 Cumberland Derby 3446 8320 2981 7814 465 SI ; 17,087 47, 54O 13,776 44,380 33" 3160 Durham 3QI4 3452 462 23.o8o 2 1 ,07 5 2OI4 Lancaster I(XOs7 8085 1072 78,880 66, ?ci I2,i;20 N orthumberland Stafford 3128 0702 2663 8743 465 IO4Q 15,726 46,660 13,644 4I,OS3 2082 47l6 Westmorland ... York N 1431 Ql ^ 1351 7983 80 1 172 8532 70.477 7066 33,881 566 5556 York W 18,609 15,937 2672 H9,356 104,276 15,080 Total for District 78,842 68,038 10,804 439,341 381,230 58,111 Table 1 225 I. Bedford 20 — 50 acres 50 — 100 acres Total area Pasture- land Arable land Total area Pasture- land Arable land 14,433 37,499 41,816 13,619 11,991 118,352 1995 12,837 70,756 41,364 30,834 6363 H,369 16,092 8418 6128 47,974 1537 9175 24,505 11,240 13,675 8070 26,130 25,724 5201 5863 70,378 458 3662 46,251 30,124 17,159 21,414 45,486 91,328 26,978 15,397 162,024 2232 17,279 109,919 97,063 56,631 9012 12,448 28,113 12,726 6651 54,172 1406 12,292 31,559 21,554 18,673 12,402 33,038 63,215 14,252 8746 107,852 826 4987 78,360 75,509 37,958 Cambridge ...... Hertford Huntingdon London Middlesex Norfolk Suffolk York E Total for District 395,496 156,476 239,020 645,751 208,606 437,H5 II. Berks 1 7. i ; ; II.O73 6082 26,0 ;o 14.7 ;4 1 1, 206 21,661 14,767 6804 43,256 2;,;6o 17,687 Hants 4 1 , 1 64 24,; 76 i6,;88 60,617 20.4O3 31,214 Kent 36,3;i 2S,2OO 98,703 52,884 Leicester 4.6. 1 38 4O.O34 6104 73*441 17,706 Northampton ... Notts 31,567 2I,6l9 24,066 9948 I ;.664 51,266 ;q,O72 32,790 20,031 18,476 30.04 1 Oxford 18.371 IO,74; 7626 34,864 17,47; 17.380 Rutland 6898 ;oio Q7Q 98;; 741 ; 244O Surrey 2;.i83 16,786 8307 40, 3Q4 22,OQ4 18.300 Sussex 46,742 32,241 14, SOI 92,798 52,836 30,462 Warwick 37,056 30,132 6924 60,831 40,872 19,959 Total for District III. Cornwall 393,2i6 88,513 268,309 40.282 124,907 48,231 651,147 i •515,682 380,768 51,83; 270,379 83,847 Devon CO 478 ;; 302 3;. 1 76 214,000 TOO ;2o IO4 480 Dorset 23,;86 17.278 6308 30,237 28,110 1 1. 127 Gloucester Hereford 43,540 28,869 33,605 20,261 9935 8608 71,052 ;o,i67 49,821 3I.;47 21,231 18,620 Monmouth Salop 30,913 46 ;oo 26,976 3;.O43 3937 55,883 45,120 47.042 10,763 26,038 Somerset 7Q 772 66 905 12,867 128,038 io;.o;o 23 888 Wilts •JQ. 177 21.601 8486 40,432 36. 3O7 1 3. 1 2 ; Worcester 36,781 26,481 10,300 58,832 37,324 21,508 Total for District IV. Chester 499,228 7O 347 343,824 40.28; 155,404 21,062 877,212 I2;,O72 542,576 7;. 446 334,636 40 626 Cumberland Derby 45,922 78,63; 31,648 67.00; 14,274 IO.73O 123,618 109,210 63,867 87.74; 59,751 21.46; 33,86Q 27,646 6223 67.030 42,;6o 2;.37Q 1 80 803 14;. 262 44.631 237.487 70.726 Northumberland Stafford 25,850 71 4O2 22,036 ;8 043 3814 I2.4;Q 41,939 IO3.83O 30,755 78.374 2;.4s6 Westmorland ... York N 28,509 66*7OQ 25,202 46 4;2 3307 20,2 ;7 61,034 I4.I, O3O 50,875 84,60; 10,159 156.42; York W 178,877 142,651 36,226 218,492 153,708 64,784 Total for District 790,013 617,030 172,983 1,189,651 785,696 403,955 226 Appendix II I. Bedford 100 — 300 acres 300 — 500 acres Total area Pasture- land Arable land Total area Pasture- land Arable land 99,411 160,222 363,616 129,047 84,744 510,080 5175 49,122 322,057 326,429 278,879 37,4" 36,997 105,050 42,864 31,373 158,495 33" 35,429 80,881 74,456 86,977 62,000 123,225 258,566 86,383 53,371 351,585 1864 13,693 241,176 251,973 191,902 70,189 106,675 176,886 100,767 53,510 304,742 1516 14,645 223,067 146,030 156,868 25,298 25,632 53,26l 28,853 20,389 92,870 922 io,355 59,140 34,899 42,012 44,891 81,043 123,625 7l,9H 33,i2i 211,872 594 4,290 163,927 111,131 114,856 Cambridge Essex Hertford Huntingdon London Middlesex Norfolk Suffolk York E Total for District 2,328,782 693,244 1,635,538 1,354,895 393>63i 961,264 II. Berks 125.782 54,325 71.457 81,124 20.732 5I.3Q2 Bucks 20"*, 76? III I 3O QI 63? 87,660 53,8lO 33.85Q Hants 2O7 78d. 78.OO4 I2Q 78o I 35.774 4I.O5 5 Q4.7IQ Kent 315,811 U8,6q8 l67,II3 I3c.c6c 64.55Q 7I,OO6 Leicester 233,455 163,880 60, {66 60,813 43,106 1 7.6 1 7 Northampton . . . Notts 238,393 2O3, i;84. 145,160 87,206 93,233 1 16,^78 138,779 67,748 82,886 25,O47 55,893 42.7OI Oxford 168,784 78,804 80,800 1 14,043 46,747 67,2Q6 Rutland •32.7Q7 10,766 I4.O3I 2O.2Q3 Q266 I I.O27 Surrey 1 2O Q85 $ 7.64O 6 3, 3 36 4. "J.OOi; 22,OO6 23. 5OQ Sussex 246.600 I27,8o6 118,704 104,025 53,6oQ 5I.3l6 Warwick 244 410 T C2 42? QI.O85 Q4 174 CO I l8 35 O56 Total for District III. Cornwall 2,342,150 268,674 1,225,042 07.702 1,117,108 170,882 1,086,512 46, 3O2 53i,i2i 17.541 555,391 28,771 Devon 602.462 •74-1 02Q 34Q. 133 I 36 5 3Q 6Q.633 66 906 Dorset i 50.536 IO3.I 11 47.423 Q7,l68 54,555 42.6 1 3 Gloucester Hereford 261,325 22Q. I4Q 167,504 I42.O43 93,82I 87,106 I2Q,828 Q2.3OQ 65,996 6O,OOS 63,832 32, 3O4 Monmouth Salop in3594 367,186 86,155 223.442 25,439 143.744 18,170 I 55.3O3 13,339 8q,8Q7 4831 6c 406 Somerset 418,523 312.412 1 06, II I 137,358 02,4.6? 44,803 Wilts 204.716 I 37,571 67,14? 1 2Q.4OO 6^.474 65.026 Worcester 201,683 H7,834 83,849 58,791 35,175 23,616 Total for District IV. Chester 2,905,848 254.Q47 1,731,195 l62,l88 1,174,653 Q2,75Q 1,001,258 26,Q2Q 562,080 10,044 439,178 788? Cumberland Derby 293,308 215.528 154,518 164,862 138,790 50,666 63,373 33,840. 38,219 2 5,640 25,154 8200 Durham 2^8 OOQ I 37.48 5 IOO 524 51.623 31.356 20,267 26? 560 1 76.O7 5 8o,4O4 28,627 21,563 7064 Northumberland Stafford 257,630 26 $ 8s i 1 76,640 175.422 80,990 OO,42O 193,523 82,Q4O 130,344 40, 3O 5 63,179 33 635 Westmorland ... York N 106,477 464 8 5 3 84,238 2 ;2.; ;o 22,239 2I2.3O3 24,574 IO6,078 19,220 6l,88o 5354 45.080 YorkW 495,186 300,351 194,835 133,570 8l,o88 52,482 Total for District 2,857,358 1,784,329 1,073,029 745,986 477,677 268,309 Table I 227 500 — 1000 ac :res ove r 1000 ac res Total area Pasture- land Arable land Total area Pasture- land Arable land I. Bedford 2Q.O2 5 12,090 16,935 5293 3411 1882 Cambridge ... 8;,4O7 17,094 68,313 23,606 4600 IQ,OO6 Essex 112,067 38,574 73,493 15,737 4788 10,949 Hertford AQ.COO 14, 1562 •54,04.7 A72O 1512 2808 Huntingdon 30,448 I3.2QI 17,1^7 4QO? 2467 2438 .Lincoln 260,87; 7">,82i i8t;,o<;4 61,178 1 8.02 1 4.2,257 London 052 952 72,707 IQ,6l7 C7.OQO 3307 2249 1058 29,893 IO.7O5 19,188 Norfolk 231, 3Q7 60,860 170,537 16,184 4380 1 1,804 Suffolk io;.i;8o 2 ;. 347 80,24.2 YorkE 105,885 26,584 79.301 — — Total for District 1,014,461 287,424 727,037 233,823 70,401 163,422 II. Berks 72,689 25,904 46,785 31,128 l6,5l6 14,612 Bucks 27,233 16,799 10,434 23QO IC78 812 Hants I 1:0,706 47,882 111,014 6;,277 2O.OIQ 44,3;8 Kent 81,088 47,106 34,882 1 6. 1 24 10,006 5128 Leicester 10,386 I4,I5Q 5227 760; C.774 1021 Northampton ... Notts 63,337 36, ;6i 36,366 12,882 26,971 2 3,67Q 13,664 Q7CQ }//i 5507 1016 •^jaj 60 60 York W 7 1.6 1 I 22 6;i 8o;8 6196 22Q2 jy-'4 Total for District 297,053 187,927 109,127 75,360 56,879 l8,48l 228 Appendix II PQ < H 13 1 w 00 » £ S 5§ g * 5 rt CO rf N oo to >J^ SO t^ O t^ rj^ rv q^ N_ oo kn P rn ^T o •O IH CN t^ r> (S « 'S ^ - \O m O »i t^ to i-i tv 2 «2° -r <5 V M Tj- « O N 1 0 M CO ON _ m co ^ ^ \0 ^ co co t^ co m •• • o * ^S ^ cT <-• liilS ll*8 1 \f\ OO Q « r» 1-1 NO g "> £ ™ *C NO~ N OO ^f •* to O O °°~ " (D^ oo_ r>- od" r* oo" d~ to tV. M \O W M 5- to M •* CO rj- N i- (S C> f^ fcT 06" CO CO SO OO u-i w rt CO co O co •i co co OO ON q, « o^ ojj oo cf N rC rT « ON >-i « tx M t^ 0 « i . lie « a 111! 1 |SS ^ HH ON OO g 0 CO Q. 8 3 v6~ 0 \0 •* O \O «O N ON N f^ «-^ N i-T r1 to oo" "i r>» M in p-c N ON IN. N \O t>. ON co ON CO N vO ^r> in "P d( yf M ON •* O sO N (S N 00 •«*• ^4- N WON ^1 M °?. 't r O^ ^P co in M. ON tx Tl- in co rj- co « )- t— 1 « ^^ « S « iS C 4> 299 • — — g (UJJ -g tj *!•§!§ 1 grtSo g Cfl ON 1-H t^ in i ^ " 3 8 $ l/» vO •* N O to \O l~^ \O "-» r» •* O ON VD NO N CO CO N "I ii« - sis -H 3fi § 3 £5° Q w c in J-N. co Tj- 8 o 2 ^ fr» • N NO" O ir» vn «O fO O O OO t-^. ON OO m cf P" «" 06" K VO O fO « •* J>^ m N Q ir\ in ao \O Tj- CO r» ON 0"

acres of agricultural »» »> > loldings here considere rt Q s ™ 4J 5 s •§ O ! H a's 1 *s rt o> <-> "^ w g S5 1 1 £ a a S « 5 g - 5 rt C rt C 3 g g 5 8 8 « sSJ 2 *j rt o v. S *S o o S c ^ o H pu, CL, < a, O V V »- - cj H (Li OH < &, S -S ° -S *• * §Ssi llJa - « 3 - OJ 3 O»— 3 TJ ** 0 1 S 5 < J H ^ S tn Jr bfi " C rt •5 Y* "3 1 s - "o S 1 1 § 8 3 1 K Jr, *s w O V tfl U M rt 2 *" K ^ Table II 229 vo vn « 0 oo ON M rt vn ON tx O tx 'tx g. VO n « "1 g 00^ CO g\ vO* ^ vn 2" g* *•. ^O «s r> O « tx •* Q vn ON NO OO cS 5 J? £ 3 £ 2 S3- § § 'S t * 1 1 a & 2 ^ | «, co . ON co co ON «N -• tx vn NO co CO CO - -. « vn vn * " " N vO vn .73 ON ON vn vo ^v OO NO ON ON OO ON ON vO t^ O\ OO *^ t'x O ^O C^ ^* ^O ^O O^ CO NO tx vn N (M co O ON ** NO tx OO N co NO oo ^f vn .ST do vn co *^- ^ 1-1 OO O co vn 5 00 tx! j^ ^f HH fX« ^O ^O tx . fx ON NO ON Tf OO O co vn 7^ vO oo ^^ tx M vn M (M "^ tx TJ- ^** *i ** t^ ^^ ci Cl 1^ NH N NH 1-1 c-i NO vO oo vn co » 0 oo CO NO tx «N ^ OO « tx tx co co *T vD ^"^ ^-N1 W iT1 tx oo tx vo ^ NO tX CO N tx vn NO •* <1 NO O « oo in rf- NO OO ON •— ' vn ON *-> ^H tx co N ^ OO tx w "3- co co o" i^ co ?! g. 8' vn fT ON co 06" f^ ON oo' ON vn OO tx tx ^t* rf V oo co '-< oo N oo ON vn OO vn co N tx OO ON ^" O vO fx (N i-. vn tx co vn O N 00 ""• vn ^" ' ON ^, co S. ^- NO ^ - 2 ^ S tx ON OO tN tx i-* Q ON vO CO O NO OO r*i \n VQ - ON - NO N NO co oo oo *? « Of Cf ~ vn «- oo fx TJ- tN ' vn tx L ^9 NH CO »-O LO Cf N co tx CO O « «N tx vn ..f* vn «£ *s*^* -V \N • CO OO OO O co O ON •* vO co c» r? 2- :- ^i. U^ 1J^ tx CO co -* *•* vn O OO tx vb SO" M 5 ° ^ t^- *o Jo O 2 s g i & 'S. «M M co NO t ~ Tf 0 vp * NO OO" tx « § ~ ' fr jt * N O tN ON OO^ CO rj- TJ OjO CO • O CO ON CO CO tX NO NO N « tt rt rt 03 CO 3 S 3 § rt 3 13 fS fj O o o o O S 2 8 2 1 3 § s § 2 rt d) « 4J rt ^ w CU « V 3 s •§ 22 13 32 -rt O 3 Jj 3 § 1 22 {3 ~ "- — ™ t: «J 22 ^ •a a s Sn 2 *^ co *"* CO •" co ™ ** co ™ •" "S) « fl) SM rt "** So o a. §5 Q g *•• U U rt IH o D 9 C v H CX, 0u, < PL, 4) VH CS <*• So o a, o 2 & I s §> o rt y ^J cj 1 1 S j> | 3 g g 3 g o a) o ^ u H PL, PH <3 PH dj t-M rt <*4 §o o cu o 8 «' «< *g 0 S 8P § 1 8P •a § 1 3 § rt o C •" u 0 C C (• C O tu -t 4) H PH PH < PU !><*•«] <*« si o a o liilf rt C rt V G •a s s s s •w h, in rt )i O B V H « H PH cx, < eu 4) **» rt V. So o a o I HI 1 ei *J C •>-' C rt ^J G •3 4) j3 "S « CO O 00 in « s> i g a, § « C >H C ^ C " c 7 c C3 IM 2 A ^ 2 2 rt 2 o 3 2 « rt O vn o ^ O 0 O o i K K ' K K •" K ° 90 W> a. I I APPENDIX III LIST OF AUTHORITIES QUOTED IN the following list the place of publication is named where it is other than London : and in the case of London publications after 1850 the •publisher's name is quoted where the British Museum Catalogue shows it. Parliamentary papers are distinguished by the printing of the letters P.P. before their title. The authorities quoted in Part I of the book (The Development of the Large Farm System and the Decay of the Small Holding) are divided according to the chapters, dealing as these do with (I) the Agricultural Revolution of the Eighteenth Century, (II) the Corn-Law Period, and (III) the First Thirty Years of Free Trade, respectively. The arrangement is as far as possible in order of publication, except that under heads II and III the few books to be cited both there and under the preceding head or heads are given in alphabetical order at the beginning of the section. The authorities quoted in Part II (The Economics of Large and Small Holdings at the Present Day) are given according to the year of publication •'rnply. A. THE DEVELOPMENT OF THE LARGE FARM SYSTEM. I. T/ie Agricultural Revolution of the Eighteenth Century. ALLEN, WILLIAM. The Landlord's Companion. 1742. ELLIS, WILLIAM. The Modern Husbandman. 1750. HILL, THOS. A Treatise of Husbandry. 1760. CONSIDERATIONS on the Present High Price of Provisions. By a West-Country Maltster. 1764. AN IMPARTIAL VIEW of English Agriculture. 1766. ESSAY ON THE NATURE and Methods of ascertaining the specific Shares of Proprietors upon the Inclosure of Common Fields. 1766. THE CAUSES OF THE DEARNESS OF PROVISIONS ASSIGNED. Gloucester. 1766. Two LFTTERS on the Flour Trade and Dearness of Corn. 1766. [FORSTER, NATHANIEL.] An Enquiry into the causes of the present high price of provisions etc. 1767. UNITING AND MONOPOLIZING FARMS. 1767. Bibliography 231 YOUNG, ARTHUR. The Farmer's Letters to the People of England. 1767. A Six Weeks' Tour through the Southern Counties of England and Wales. 1768. PENNINGTON, W. Reflections on the Various Advantages resulting from the draining, inclosing and allotting of large commons and common fields. 1769. WIMPEY, JOSEPH. Thoughts upon several Interesting Subjects. 1770. PETERS, MATTHEW. The Rational Farmer. 2nd ed. 1771. YOUNG, ARTHUR. The Farmer's Tour through the East of England. 1771. COMBER, T. Real Improvements in Agriculture. 1772. A SKETCH OF A PLAN for reducing the present high price of corn. 1772. THE ADVANTAGES AND DISADVANTAGES of Inclosing Waste Lands and Open Fields. By a Country Gentleman. 1772. ADDINGTON, STEPHEN. An Inquiry into the Reasons for and against inclosing Open Fields. Coventry. 2nd ed. 1772. YOUNG, ARTHUR. Political Essays. 1772. [ARBUTHNOT, JOHN.] An Inquiry into the connection between the present price of provisions and the size of farms. By a Farmer. 1773. MOORE, FRANCIS. Considerations on the exorbitant Price of Provisions. 1773. PRICE, RICHARD. Observations on Reversionary Payments. 2nd ed. 1773. YOUNG, ARTHUR. Rural Economy. 1770. Political Arithmetic. 1774. AN HUMBLE ADDRESS to the King concerning the Dearness of Provisions. 1775. KENT, NATHANIEL. Hints to Gentlemen of Landed Property. 1775. KAMES, LORD (H. Home). The Gentleman Farmer. Edinburgh. 1776. PETERS, MATTHEW. Agricultura. 1776. FORBES, FRANCIS. The Improvement of Waste Lands. 1778. AN ENQUIRY INTO THE ADVANTAGES and Disadvantages resulting from Bills of Inclosure. 1780. OBSERVATIONS on a Pamphlet entitled: 'An Enquiry into the Advantages and Disadvantages resulting from Bills of Inclosure.' Shrewsbury. 1781. ANNALS OF AGRICULTURE. Collected and published by Arthur Young. 46 vols. 1784-1815. A POLITICAL ENQUIRY into the Consequences of inclosing waste lands and the causes of the present high price of Butchers' Meat. Being the sentiments of a Society of Farmers in shire. 1785. STONE, THOMAS. An Essay on Agriculture. Lynn. 1785. CURSORY REMARKS on Inclosures by a Country Farmer. 1786. MARSHALL, WILLIAM. The Rural Economy of Norfolk. 1787. STONE, THOMAS. Suggestions for rendering the inclosure of common fields and waste lands a source of population and of riches. 1787. MARSHALL, WILLIAM. The Rural Economy of Yorkshire. 1788. ADAM, — . Practical Essays on Agriculture. 1789. MARSHALL, WILLIAM. The Rural Economy of the Midland Counties. 1790. SINCLAIR, SIR JOHN. The Statistical Account of Scotland. Edinburgh. 1793. ANDERSON, JAMES. A General View of the Agriculture of Aberdeenshire. Board of Agriculture. Edinburgh. 1794. BROWN, THOMAS. A General View of the Agriculture of Derbyshire. Board of Agriculture. 1794. 232 Appendix III DONALDSON, JAMES. A General View of the Agriculture of Northamptonshire. Board of Agriculture. Edinburgh. 1794. PEARCE, WILLIAM. A General View of the Agriculture of Berkshire. Board of Agriculture. 1794. PRINGLE, ANDREW. A General View of the Agriculture of Westmorland. Board of Agriculture. Edinburgh. 1794. WEDGE, THOMAS. A General View of the Agriculture of Cheshire. Board of Agriculture. 1794. WINCHILSEA, EARL OF. Letter on the Allotment Question. In Communications to the Board of Agriculture. Vol. I, p. 83. 1794. DAVIES, DAVID. The Case of Labourers in Husbandry stated and considered. 1795- DONALDSON, J. Modern Agriculture. Edinburgh. 1795. HODSON, S. An Address to the Different Classes of Persons in Great Britain. 1795. P.P. HIGH PRICE OF PROVISIONS. Second Report from the Committee appointed to consider of the present. Reprints. Vol. IX, p. 706. 1795. WRIGHT, THOMAS. A Short Address to the Public on the Monopoly of Small Farms. 1795. ESSAYS ON AGRICULTURE. Occasioned by reading Mr Stone's Report on... the County of Lincoln. [B. M. Catalogue under Stone, Thos.] 1796. KENT, NATHANIEL. A General View of the Agriculture of Norfolk. Board of Agriculture. Norwich. 1796. MARSHALL, WILLIAM. The Rural Economy of Gloucestershire. 2nd ed. 1796. P. P. WASTE LANDS. First Report from the Committee appointed to take into consideration the Cultivation and Improvement of the Waste, Uninclosed and Unproductive Lands of the Kingdom. Reports, Miscellaneous, 1795-6. Vol. XLVIII. 1796. PITT, WILLIAM. A General View of the Agriculture of Staffordshire. Board of Agriculture. 1796. ROBERTSON, THOMAS. Outline of the General Report upon the Size of Farms. Edinburgh. 1796. EDEN, SIR FREDERICK MORTON. The State of the Poor. 1797. ANDERSON, JAMES. Essays relating to Agriculture. 2nd ed. 1799. BILLINGSLEY, JOHN. A General View of the Agriculture of Somersetshire. Board of Agriculture. Bath. 1798. MIDDLETON, JOHN. A General View of the Agriculture of Middlesex. Board of Agriculture. 1798. YOUNG, ARTHUR. A General View of the Agriculture of Lincolnshire. Board of Agriculture. 1799. HOLT, JOHN. A General View of the Agriculture of Lancaster. Board of Agri- culture. 1794. MONK, JOHN. A General View of the Agriculture of Leicestershire. Board of Agriculture. 1 794. COMMUNICATIONS to the Board of Agriculture. 1797-1813. GIRDLER, J. S. Observations on the Pernicious Consequences of Forestalling, Regrating and Ingrossing. 1800. YOUNG, ARTHUR. The Question of Scarcity plainly stated and Remedies con- sidered. 1800. Bibliography 233 SINCLAIR, SIR JOHN. Observations on the Means of enabling a Cottager to keep a Cow. 1801. THAER, ALBRECHT DANIEL. Einleitung zur Kenntniss in die englische Land- wirthschaft. Hanover. 1801. HARTLEY, NEHEMIAH. Some Cursory Observations on the Conversion of Pasture Land into Tillage. Bath. 1802. CHALMERS, GEORGE. An Estimate of the Comparative Strength of Great Britain. A New Edition, corrected and continued to 1801. 1802. HUNTER, A. Georgical Essays. York. 1803. PLYMLEY, JOSEPH. A General View of the Agriculture of Shropshire. Board of Agriculture. 1803. MARSHALL, WILLIAM. A Treatise on the Landed Property of England. 1804. YOUNG, ARTHUR. A General View of the Agriculture of Suffolk. Board of Agriculture. 1 804. DUNCUMB, JOHN. A General View of the Agriculture of the County of Hereford. Board of Agriculture. 1805. SELKIRK, EARL OF. Observations on the Present State of the Highlands of Scotland. 2nd ed. Edinburgh. 1806. RUDGE, THOMAS. A General View of the Agriculture of Gloucestershire. Board of Agriculture. 1 807. THAER, ALBRECHT DANIEL. Der praktische Ackerbau von R. W. Dickson. Berlin. 1807. THE COMPLETE ENGLISH FARMER. 1807. ENCLOSURES, General Report on. Board of Agriculture. 1808. BATCHELOR, THOMAS. A General View of the Agriculture of Bedfordshire. Board of Agriculture. 1808. HOLLAND, HENRY. A General View of the Agriculture of Cheshire. Board of Agriculture. 1808. MAYOR, WILLIAM. A General View of the Agriculture of Berks. Board of Agriculture. 1808. VANCOUVER, CHARLES. A General View of the Agriculture of Devonshire. Board of Agriculture. 1808. YOUNG, ARTHUR, JUN. A General View of the Agriculture of Sussex. Board of Agriculture. 1808. PUT, WILLIAM. A General View of the Agriculture of Leicestershire. Board of Agriculture. 1809. YOUNG, ARTHUR. A General View of the Agriculture of Oxfordshire. Board of Agriculture. 1809. DAVIS, THOMAS. A General View of the Agriculture of Wiltshire. Board of Agriculture. 2nd ed. 1811. WORGAN, G. B. A General View of the Agriculture of Cornwall. Board of Agriculture. 1811. BROWN, ROBERT. A Treatise on Rural Affairs. Edinburgh. 1811. STRICKLAND, H. E. A General View of the Agriculture of the East Riding of Yorkshire. Board of Agriculture. York. 1812. YOUNG, ARTHUR. An Enquiry into the Progressive Value of Money in England, as marked by the price of agricultural products. 1812. BAILEY, JOHN, AND CULLEY, GEORGE. A General View of the Agriculture of Northumberland. Board of Agriculture. 3rd ed. 1813. 234 Appendix III MURRAY, ADAM. A General View of the Agriculture of Warwickshire. Board of Agriculture. 1813. PRIEST, ST JOHN. A General View of the Agriculture of Buckingham. Board of Agriculture. 1813. DICKSON, R. W. A General View of the Agriculture of Lancashire. Board of Agriculture. 1815. P.P. CORN LAWS, Report from the Select Committee on. S. P. 1813-14, No. 339. Vol. III. P.P. GRAIN AND THE CORN LAWS, Reports from the Lords' Committee re- specting. S. P. 1814-15, No. 26. Vol. v. SINCLAIR, SIR JOHN. Report on the Agricultural State of Scotland. Edinburgh. 1814. FAREY, JOHN. A General View of the Agriculture of Derbyshire. Board of Agriculture. 1815. MALTHUS, THOMAS ROBERT. Essay on the Principle of Population as it affects the future improvement of society. 5th ed. 1817. SINCLAIR, SIR JOHN. The Code of Agriculture. 1817. SMITH, ADAM. An Enquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. 2nd ed. 1817. GOOCH, WILLIAM. A General View of the Agriculture of Cambridgeshire. Board of Agriculture. 1813. BRERETON, C. D. Observations on the Administration of the Poor Laws in Agricultural Districts. Norwich. 2nd ed. 1824. THE LABOURERS' FRIEND MAGAZINE. 1834-42. WELFORD, RICHARD GRIFFITHS. How will Free Trade in Corn affect the Farmer? James Ridgway. 1843. PERRY, G. W. The Peasantry of England. Gilpin. 1846. PORTER, GEORGE RICHARDSON. Progress of the Nation. New ed. 1851. TOOKE, THOMAS (and NEWMARCH, W.). A History of Prices and of the state of the Circulation from 1793 to 1856. Longmans. 1857. P.P. AGRICULTURE. CHILDREN'S, YOUNG PERSONS' AND WOMEN'S EMPLOY- MENT IN, Reports of the Commissioners on. First Report. S. P. 1867-8. Vol. xvn. [4068, 4068 l.] Second Report. S. P. 1868-9. Vol. xm. [4201,4202.] BRODRICK, HON. GEORGE CHARLES. English Land and English Landlords. Cobden Club. 1881. RAE, JOHN. Why have the Yeomanry perished ? Contemporary Review. Vol. XLIV, p. 94. 1883. ROGERS, JAMES EDWIN THOROLD. Six Centuries of Work and Wages. Sonnen- schein. 1884. TOYNBEE, ARNOLD. Lectures on the Industrial Revolution in England. Riving- tons. 1884. PROTHERO, ROWLAND EDMUND. The Pioneers and Progress of English Farming. Longmans. 1888. P.P. SMALL HOLDINGS REPORT, 1889. From the Select Committee on Small Holdings. S.P. 1890, No. 223. Vol. xvn. STUBBS, CHARLES WILLIAM. The Land and the Labourers. Stereotyped ed. Sonnenschein. 1891. Bibliography 235 ROGERS, J. D. "Yeoman." In Pa/grave's Dictionary. Vol. in, p. 886. 1891-9. ROGERS, JAMES EDWIN THOROLD. Industrial and Commercial History of England. 1892. LEFEVRE, GEO. J. SHAW (Lord Eversley). Agrarian Tenures. Cassell and Co. i893- TRAILL, HENRY DUFF (ed. by). Social England. Cassell and Co. 1893-7. BRENTANO, Lujo. Erbrechtspolitik. Stuttgart. 1899. EYRE, G. F., AND KYLE, J. L. Small Farming. Oxford, Horace Hart. 1902. LEVY, HERMANN. Die Not der englischen Landwirte zur Zeit der hohen Getreidezolle. Stuttgart. 1902. WALPOLE, SIR SPENCER. A History of England from the conclusion of the great war in 1815. Longmans. Ed. of 1902. THOMPSON, HUBERT GORDON. The Canal System of England. Cobden Club. 1903. LEVY, HERMANN. Der Untergang klein-bauerlicher Betriebe in England. In Conrad's Jahrbiichern for 1903. HASBACH, WILHELM. Der Untergang des englischen Bauernstandes in neuer Beleuchtung. In Archiv fur Sozialwissenschaft. Vol. XXIV. 1906. - A History of the English Agricultural Labourer. English Edition. P. S. King and Son. 1908. JOHNSON, ARTHUR HENRY. The Disappearance of the Small Landowner. Oxford, Clarendon Press. 1909. GRAY, H. L. Yeoman Farming in Oxfordshire. In Quarterly Journal of Economics, pp. 293 ff. 1910. II. The Corn-Law Period. BRERETON, C. D. Wages etc. See above, p. 234. BRODRICK, GEO. C. English Land and English Landlords. See above, p. 234. THE LABOURERS' FRIEND. See above, p. 234. LEVY, HERMANN. Die Not etc. See above, p. 235. STUBBS, C. W. The Land and the Labourers. See above, p. 234. TOOKE'S History of Prices. See above, p. 234. WALPOLE'S History. See above, p. 235. WELFORD, R. G. How will Free Trade affect the Farmer? See above, p. 234. LAWRENCE, CHARLES. Practical Directions for the Cultivation of Cottage Gardens. 1831. LABOURERS' FRIEND SOCIETY, Proceedings of the. 1832 ff. P. P. AGRICULTURE. Report from the Select Committee on Agriculture. S. P. 1833, No. 612. Vol. v. BAKER, R. On the Farming of Essex. In Journal of the Royal Agricultural Society. Vol. v. 1835. P.P. AGRICULTURAL DISTRESS. Reports from the Select Committee on the State of Agriculture. S. P. 1836, Nos. 79, 189, 465. Vol. Vlll. FARMERS' MAGAZINE, THE, for 1836. P.P. AGRICULTURAL DISTRESS. Report from the Select Committee of the House of Lords on the State of Agriculture. S.P. 1837, No. 464. Vol. v. 236 Appendix III CARMICHAEL, — . Corn Laws. Edinburgh and London. 1838. ANTI-CORN LAW CONFERENCE, Report of the Statistical Committee appointed by the. [B. M. Catalogue under London, ill.] 1842. P.P. HANDLOOM WEAVERS, Reports from Assistant Commissioners on. S. P. 1840, Nos. 217, 220. Vols. xxin, xxiv. ANTI-CORN LAW MEETING, Report of the Great. 1842. NOEL, BAPTIST WRIOTHESLEY. A Plea for the Poor : how the Repeal of the Corn Laws will affect the Working Classes. 1842. P.P. AGRICULTURE. EMPLOYMENT OF WOMEN AND CHILDREN IN. Reports of the Special Assistant Commissioners on. S. P. 1843, No. 510. Vol. XII. LAING, SAMUEL. National Distress. 1844. BUCKLAND, G. On the Farming of Kent. In Journal of the Royal Agricultural Society. Vol. vi. 1845. ENGELS, FRIEDRICH. Die Lage der arbeitenden Klassen in England. (Trans., by F. K. Wischnewetsky, as The Condition of the Working Classes in England. Swan Sonnenschein. 1892.) Leipzig. 1845. KARKEEK, W. F. On the Farming of Cornwall. In Journal of the Royal Agri- cultural Society. Vol. vi. 1845. THORNTON, WILLIAM THOS. Over-Population and its Remedy. Longmans. 1846. LEGARD, G. On the Farming of the East Riding of Yorkshire. In Journal of the Royal Agricultural Society. VoL IX. 1848. RAYNBIRD, WILLIAM AND HUGH. On the Agriculture of Suffolk. 1849. MARTINEAU, HARRIET. History of England during the Thirty Years' Peace, 1816-46. 1849-50. ACLAND, SIR THOMAS DYKE, AND STURGE, W. The Farming of Somersetshire. 1851. CAIRO, SIR JAMES. English Agriculture in 1850-51. Longmans. 1851. BEGGS, T. Freehold Land Societies. In Journal of the Royal Statistical Society. Vol. xvi. 1853. DUNKLEY, H. The Charter of the Nations. 1854. PEEL, SIR ROBERT, Memoirs by. Published by Earl Stanhope and E. Cardwell. 1856-7. COBDEN, RICHARD. Speeches on Questions of Public Policy. Ed. by John Bright and J. E. Thorold Rogers. London and Oxford. 1870. ONSLOW, EARL OF. Landlords and Allotments. 1886. BRENTANO, Lujo. Anfang und Ende der englischen Kornzolle. A supplement to the Allgemeine Zeitung. Nr. 15, p. 4. 1892. HEATH, RICHARD. The English Peasant. Fisher Unwin. 1893. NlCHOLLS, SIR GEORGE. A History of the English Poor Law. New ed. P. S. King and Son. 1898-9. LEVY, HERMANN. Landarbeiter und Kornzolle. In the Nation, Nov. 2nd. 1901. Fox, ARTHUR WILSON. Agricultural Wages during the last Fifty Years. In Journal of the Royal Statistical Society. Vol. LXVi. 1903. Bibliography 237 III. The First Thirty Years of Free Trade. BROWN, R. A Treatise etc. See above, p. 233. CAIRD, J. English Agriculture. See above, p. 236. P.P. AGRICULTURE. EMPLOYMENT OF WOMEN AND CHILDREN IN. Second Report of the Commissioners. See above, p. 236. KENT, NATHANIEL. Hints, etc. See above, p. 231. LEFEVRE, G. SHAW. Agrarian Tenures. See above, p. 235. LEVY, H. Die Not etc. See above, p. 235. P.P. SMALL HOLDINGS REPORT, 1889. See above, p. 234. ROBERTSON, TH. Outlines of the General Report. See above, p. 232. SINCLAIR, SIR JOHN. The Statistical Account. See above, p. 231. THORNTON, W. T. Over-population. See above, p. 236. WALPOLE, SPENCER. History. See above, p. 235. YOUNG, ARTHUR. Rural Economy. See above, p. 231. MARSHALL, WILLIAM. Treatise. See above, p. 233. SINCLAIR, SIR JOHN. An Account of the Systems of Husbandry adopted in the more improved districts of Scotland. Edinburgh. Ed. of 1812. RUSSELL, JOSEPH. A Treatise on Practical and Chemical Agriculture. Warwick. 1831. BACON, RICHARD N. Report on the Agriculture of Norfolk. London and Norwich. 1844. Low, DAVID. On Landed Property. 1844. ALISTER, R. Barriers to the National Prosperity of Scotland. Edinburgh, Johnstone and Hunter. London, Simpkin, Marshall and Co. 1853. MILL, JOHN STUART. Principles of Political Economy. 6th ed. 1855. BELL, DR. Report on the Farming of Durham. In Journal of the Royal Agricultural Society. Vol. xvn. 1856. THE JOURNAL OF AGRICULTURE. New Series. Edinburgh, Blackwood. July 1857— March 1859. POGGENDORF, A. Die Landwirtschaft in England. Leipzig. 1860. SPEARING, J. B. Report on the Farming of Berkshire. In Journal of the Royal Agricultural Society. Vol. XXI. 1860. GURDON, JOHN. On Co-operative Farms at Assington. \n Journal of the Royal Agricultural Society. Vol. xxiv. 1863. CADLE, CLEMENT. On the Agriculture of Worcestershire. In Journal of the Royal Agricultural Society. 2nd series. Vol. ill. 1867. NOBLE, JOHN. Fiscal Legislation, 1842-65. 1867. WEBSTER, CRAYSTON. On the Farming of Westmorland. In Journal of the Royal Agricultural Society. 2nd series. Vol. IV. 1868. TRASH, — . On Allotments. In the Country Gentleman's Magazine. Vol. vi. 1871. FARRALL, T. Report on the Agriculture of Cumberland. In Journal of 'the Royal Agricultural Society. 2nd series. Vol. X. Part II. 1874. CAIRD, SIR JAMES. A General View of British Agriculture. In Journal of the Royal Agricultural Society. 2nd series. Vol. XI v. Part 1 1. 1878. The Landed Interest and the Supply of Food. Cassell. 1878. 238 Appendix, III P.P. STATISTICAL ABSTRACT FOR THE U. K. No. 28. S.P. 1881, VoL xcni (C. 2935). P.P. AGRICULTURE. Report of the Royal Commission on the Depressed Condition of the Agricultural Interest. 1880-2. See below, under B, p. 238. P.P. AGRICULTURE. Reports of the Royal Commission on Agricultural De- pression, 1894-7. See below, under B, p. 239. STIRTON, THOMAS. Small Holdings. In Journal of the Royal Agricultural Society. 3rd series. Vol. V. 1894. BOWLEY, ARTHUR L. Wages in the United Kingdom. Cambridge University Press. 1900. PROTHERO, ROWLAND EDMUND. English Agriculture in the Reign of Queen Victoria. \^i\ Journal of the Royal Agricultural Society. 3rd series. Vol. x. 1901. SOMERVILLE, WILLIAM. Agricultural Progress in the Nineteenth Century. In the Bath and West and Southern Counties Journal. Vol. XII. 1902. P.P. MEMORANDA, Statistical Tables and Charts prepared in the Board of Trade. S. P. 1903, Vol. LXVII (Cd. 1761). P.P. WHOLESALE AND RETAIL PRICES. S.P. 1903, No. 321. Vol. LXVIII. B. THE ECONOMICS OF LARGE AND SMALL HOLDINGS AT THE PRESENT DAY. LAWSON, WILLIAM; HUNTER, C. D. ; and others. Ten Years of Gentleman Farming at Blennerhassett. 2nd ed. 1875. P.P. AGRICULTURE. Report of the Royal Commission on the Depressed Con- dition of the Agricultural Interest, 1880-2. Preliminary Report. S.P. 1881, Vol. XV (C. 2778). Minutes, Vol. xvi (C. 2778*), and VoL xvil (C. 3096). Report and Minutes of Evidence. S. P. 1882, Vol. xiv (C. 3309). Reports of Assistant Commissioners. S.P. 1880, Vol. xvni (C. 2678). „ „ „ S.P. 1 88 1, Vol. XVI (C. 2778 2, and C. 2951). S.P. 1882, Vol. xv (C. 3375). BRODRICK, HON. GEORGE CHARLES. English Land and English Landlords. Cobden Club. 1881. BURROWS, ALFRED J. The Agricultural Depression and how to meet it. Simpkin, Marshall and Co. 1882. RAE, JOHN. Why have the Yeomanry perished ? In Contemporary Review, Vol. XLIV. 1883. P.P. AGRICULTURAL RETURNS for 1885. S. P. 1884-5, V<>1- LXXXIV (C. 4537). CHAMBERLAIN, JOSEPH (PREFACE BY). The Radical Programme. Chapman and Hall. 1885. IMPEY, FREDERICK. Three Acres and a Cow. Sonnenschein. 1886. BURN, ROBERT SCOTT. Systematic Small Farming. Crosby, Lockwood and Co. 1886. Bibliography 239 COLEBROOKE, SIR JAMES EDWARD. Small Holdings and School Fees. 2nd ed. Edinburgh. 1886. ONSLOW, WILLIAM HILHER, EARL OF. Landlords and Allotments. Longmans. 1886. READ, CLARE SEWELL. Large and Small Holdings. In Journal of the Royal Agricultural Society. 2nd series. Vol. xxin, Pt. I. 1887. SUTTON, MARTIN J. Permanent and Temporary Pastures. 3rd ed. Hamilton, Adams and Co. 1888. P.P. ALLOTMENTS AND SMALL HOLDINGS in Great Britain. Return of. S. P. 1890, Vol. LVII (C. 6144). P.P. SMALL HOLDINGS REPORT, 1889. From the Select Committee on Small Holdings. S.P. 1890, No. 223. Vol. xvn. WRIGHTSON, JOHN. The Agricultural Lessons of the Eighties. In Journal of the Royal Agricultural Society. 3rd series. Vol. I. 1890. BEAR, WILLIAM E. The Survival in Farming. In Journal of the Royal Agri- cultural Society. 3rd series. Vol. II. 1891. MCCONNELL, PRIMROSE. Experiences of a Scotsman on the Essex Clays. In Journal of the Royal Agricultural Society. 3rd series. Vol. n. 1891. STEPHENS, HENRY. The Book of the Farm. 1772. 4th ed., revised and in great part re- written by Jas. Macdonald. Blackwood. 1891. TEGETMEIER, W. B. Farm Poultry. In Journal of the Royal Agricultural Society. 3rd series. Vol. II. 1891. GRAHAM, P. ANDERSON. The Rural Exodus. Methuen and Co. 1892. HARRIS, W. J., and others. Land, its Attractions and Riches. 1892. LAWRY, J. W. Small Holdings in Cornwall. In Journal of 'the Royal Agricultural Society. 3rd series. Vol. ill. 1892. LONG, PROF. JAMES, and others. A Handbook for Farmers and Small Holders. Sampson, Low, Marston and Co. 1892, BEAR, WILLIAM E. A Study of Small Holdings. Cobden Club. 1893. KEBBEL, THOMAS EDWARD. The Agricultural Labourer. 3rd ed. W. H. Allen and Co. 1 893. LEFEVRE, GEO. SHAW (Lord Eversley). Agrarian Tenures. Cassell and Co. 1893. SHELDON, PROF. JOHN PRINCE. The Future of British Agriculture. W. H. Allen and Co. 1893. STIRTON, THOMAS. Small Holdings. In Journal of the Royal Agricultural Society. 3rd series. Vol. v. 1894. P.P. AGRICULTURE. Report of the Royal Commission on Agricultural De- pression, 1894-7. First Report. S.P. 1894, Vol. xvi (C. 7400). Second Report. S. P. 1896, Vol. xvi (C. 7981). Final Report. S.P. 1897, Vol. XV (C. 8540). Evidence and Appendices. S. P. 1894, Vol. xvi (C. 7400). Further Evidence and Appendices. S. P. 1896, Vol. XVII (C. 8021, 8146). Appendices. S. P. 1897, Vol. XV (C. 8541, 8300). Report on the Isle of Axholme and Districts of Essex, by R. Hunter Pringle. S.P. 1894, Vol. xvi, Part I (C. 7374). Report on Lincolnshire, by A. Wilson Fox. S.P. 1895, Vol. xvi (C. 7671)- 240 Appendix III Report on North Devon, by R. Henry Rew. S.P. 1895, Vol. xvi (C. 7728). Report on the Poultry Rearing and Fattening Industry of the Heathfield district of Sussex, by R. Henry Rew. S.P. 1895, Vol. xvi (C. 7623). P.P. AGRICULTURAL HOLDINGS. Returns as to the Number and Size of Agri- cultural Holdings in Great Britain in the Year 1895. S.P. 1896, VoL LXVil (C. 8243). GREEN, J. L. Allotments and Small Holdings. Swan Sonnenschein and Co. 1896. MALDEN, WALTER J. Recent Changes in Farm Practices. In Journal of the Royal Agricultural Society. 3rd series. Vol. vn. 1896. CHANNING, FRANCIS ALLSTON. The Truth about Agricultural Depression. Longmans. 1897. MALDEN, WALTER J. The Conversion of Arable Land to Pasture. Kegan Paul. 1898. NATIONAL POULTRY ORGANISATION SOCIETY. Leaflets. 1898 etc. BEAR, WILLIAM E. Flower and Fruit Growing. In Journal of the Royal Agri- cultural Society. 3rd series. Vol. x. 1899. GRAHAM, P. ANDERSON. The Revival of English Agriculture. Jarrold and Sons. 1899. STILLICH, O. Die englische Agrarkrisis. Jena. 1899. BEAR, WILLIAM E. Fumigation for Insect Pests. In Journal of the Royal Agri- cultural Society. 3rd series. Vol. xi, Part II. 1900. BROWN, EDWARD. The British Egg Supply. In Journal of the Royal Agri- cultural Society. 3rd series. Vol. XI. 1900. P. P. WAGES AND EARNINGS of Agricultural Labourers. Report by A. Wilson Fox. S.P. 1900, Vol. LXXXII (Cd. 346). AGRICULTURAL ORGANISATION SOCIETY. First (Second etc.) Report of. 1901 etc. CENTRAL CHAMBER OF AGRICULTURE. Proceedings of the. 1901. CHARLETON, W. L., and others. Small Holdings and Co-operation. Newark. 1901. CO-OPERATIVE ALLIANCE. Report of Proceedings at the Fifth Congress of the. 1902. EYRE, G. F., AND KYLE, J. L. Small Farming. Oxford, Horace Hart. 1902. GLOUCESTERSHIRE COUNTY COUNCIL. Annual Report of its Technical In- struction Committee for 1901-2. 1902. HAGGARD, HENRY RIDER. Rural England. Longmans. 1902. LEVY, HERMANN. Die Not der englischen Landwirte zur Zeit der hohen Getreide- zolle. Stuttgart. 1902. SAMUEL, HERBERT. Liberalism. Grant Richards. 1902. WALKER, — . Small Farming. In Journal of the Bath and West and Southern Counties Society. 1902. P.P. AGRICULTURAL RETURNS for 1903. S.P. 1904, Vol. cv (Cd. 2131). THE COUNTRY GENTLEMAN'S ESTATE BOOK for 1903, etc. CRAGG, A. R. Specialities in Farming. In Journal of the Bath and West and Southern Counties Society. 1903. DAVID, EDUARD. Sozialismus und Landwirtschaft. Berlin. 1903. DRUCE, S. B. L. On Small Holdings. In Journal of the Farmers* Club. November, 1903. Bibliography 24 1 Fox, ARTHUR WILSON. Agricultural Wages during the last Fifty Years. In Journal of the Royal Statistical Society. Vol. LXVi. 1903. GRAHAM, P. ANDERSON. The Revival of Agriculture. In the Morning Post. April ii, 1903. LEVY, HERMANN. Die Lage der englischen Landwirtschaft in der Gegenwart. In Conrad's Jahrbiichern for 1903. Landarbeiterfrage und Landflucht in England. In Brauns Archiv for 1903. Landwirtschaftlicher Export in England. In Conrad 's Jahrbiichern for 1903. Review of Dr. David's Sozialismus und Landivirtscha/t. In Deutschland. Nov. 1903. MATTHEWS, A. T. Tenant Farmers as Breeders of Pedigree Stock. In Journal of the Bath and West and Southern Counties Society. 1903. P.P. MEMORANDA, Statistical Tables and Charts prepared in the Board of Trade. S.P. 1903, Vol. LXVII (Cd. 1761). REW, R. HENRY. Recent Changes in the number of Cattle and Sheep in Great Britain. \r^ Journal of the Farmers' Club. 1903. P.P. SMALL HOLDINGS. Return showing the number of instances in which, between June 24th, 1897, and March 3ist, 1902, Local Authorities acquired Land. ..by compulsory purchase, etc. S.P. 1903, No. 182. Vol. Lix. THONGER, C. G. FREER. Some Essentials of Successful Dairying. In Journal of the Bath and West and Southern Counties Society. 1903. P.P. REPORT ON WHOLESALE AND RETAIL PRICES IN 1902. S.P. 1903, No. 321. Vol. LXVIII. LEVY, HERMANN. Die Lage der englischen Landwirtschaft in der Gegenwart. In Conrad's Jahrbiichern for 1904. MATTHEWS, A. T. The Position and Prospects of Stock-Farming. In Journal of the Bath and West and Southern Counties Society. 1905. P. P. FOOD. Report of the Royal Commission on the Supply of Food and Raw Material in Time of War. S. P. 1905, Vols. xxxix, XL (Cd. 2547, 2552, 2596). BLUNT, WILFRID SCAWEN. Possibilities of Peasant Ownership in Sussex. In the Nineteenth Century. Vol. LIX. 1906. COLLINGS, JESSE. Land Reform. Longmans. 1906. MARKET-DAY LECTURES, 1905-6. Chelmsford. 1906. MOORE, HAROLD E. Our Heritage in the Land. P. S. King and Son. 1906. PRATT, EDWIN A. The Transition in Agriculture. John Murray. 1906. P.P. SMALL HOLDINGS. Report of the Departmental Committee appointed by the Board of Agriculture to enquire into the subject of Small Holdings in Great Britain. S. P. 1906, Vol. LV (Cd. 3277, 3278). BELGARD, M. Parzellierung und Innere Kolonisation. Leipzig. 1907. JEBB, L. The Small Holdings of England. John Murray. 1907. THE LAND POLICY OF THE GOVERNMENT. In the Quarterly Review. Vol. ccvn. 1907. BEAR, W. E. Prospects for Small Holdings. In Journal of the Bath and West and Southern Counties Society. 1908. UDALE, JAMES. Market Gardening in the Vale of Evesham. In Journal of the Royal Agricultural Society. Vol. LXIX. 1908. SHELDON, PROF. JOHN PRINCE. The Farm and the Dairy. 4th ed. Geo. Bell and Sons. 1908. L. 16 242 Appendix III SMALL HOLDINGS ACTS, Report of a Conference as to the Administration of the. 1908. P.P. TRADE AND NAVIGATION. Monthly Accounts relating to, for 1908. S. P. 1908, No. 25. Vols. cv, cvi. BOARD OF AGRICULTURE, Journal of the, for 1908-9. IMPEY, FREDERICK. Small Holdings in England. P. S. King and Son. 1909. NEWSHAM, J. C. Strawberry Growing in Hampshire. In Journal of the Board of Agriculture. June, 1909. PARKER, SIR GILBERT. The Land for the People. 1909. PRATT, EDWIN A. Small Holders : What they must do to succeed. P. S. King and Son. 1909. RADFORD, G. Agricultural Co-operation. P. S. King and Son. n. d. P.P. AGRICULTURAL STATISTICS for 1909. Pt. i. S. P. 1910. (Cd. 5064.) P.P. STATISTICAL ABSTRACT for the United Kingdom, for 1909. S.P. 1910. (Cd. 5296.) WILKINS, L. (Miss L. Jebb). The Small Holdings Controversy. P. S. King and Son. 1910. LAND CLUB MOVEMENT, THE. Land Club League. 2nd ed. 1910. OUR LAND AND LAND CLUB NEWS. Land Club League. Feb. 1910. P.P. SMALL HOLDINGS, Annual Report on. S. P. 1910. (Cd. 5180.) INDEX Acts of Parliament: see Allotment Acts, Legis- lative Action, Small Holdings Acts. Agricultural Depression : 9, 46-49; 56, 76 f., 82 f., 87 f., ioif., 108-13. Agricultural Holdings Act: 138 f. Agricultural Organisation Society, the: 152 n., 190 f., 195, 197, 210. Agricultural Science: 15, 20, 41, 44, 48, 56 f., 59 f., 62-5, 68, 71 f., 79-81, 83 f., 86, 96, 155, 160, 176 f., 182, 204, 208 f., 219-21. Agricultural revival: 87, 210. Alconbury : 24 a. 4. Alister, R. ; cited: 55. Allotment Acts : 51, 125, 126, 130, 141, 143. Allotments: 36 f., 42-44, 51-4, 64 n. 3, 66 f., 88 f., 90, 92, 94, 96-8, 104-8, 1 10, in, 116, 122 f., 125, 130, 149, 157, 158, i59» I<55» 167, 175, 215, 217. See also under Labourers' Holdings, Landlord^. Allowance System, the: 12. Anderson, James; cited: 20, 27. Anti-Corn Law League, the : 54 n. 3. Arable districts : 65, 67-9, 103-5, IIO> 183 n., 189. Arable land : percentage of agricultural land; 103-5. percentage on various units; 105. Set also Corn-growing. Arbuthnot, J. ; cited: 13, 19, 29, 39 n. 5. Areas of various types of holding : 17, 88-90, 92 f., 99. Artisans as small holders: 215-22. Asquith, H. H. ; cited: 146. Assmgton: 187 f. Axholme, Isle of: 85, 90, 106, 107, 109 f., 165, 189, 214. Aylestone: 151 Baggrow: 188. Bailiffs: 102, 161, 217. Baines, M. T.: 149. Bargaining ; large holder's advantage in : 164 f. Baring, Sir Francis : 64. Baskets, issued by G.E.R. : 196. Batchelor, George: 216. Beans: 13, 18, 209. Bear, W. E.; cited: 84, 85 n., 90 n., 107, 109 n., no, 140 n., 151, 164, 165 n., 183 n. Bedfordshire : 1 10. Belgard, M.; cited: 214. Birmingham: 116, 216. Blennerhasset : 188. Blyth, Sir James: 151. Board of Agriculture, the: 15, 29, 43, 51. Reports published by: 29, 32. Board of Agriculture and Fisheries, the : 97 n., 125, 127 £, 131, 147-9, '5* n-» 190, 221. Borrowing, by yeomen: 26. See also Mortgages. Bounty on Corn : 10. Brandsby: 193. Bread: 9, 12, 13, 58, 201, 202 f., 210, 212. Brodrick, G. C.; cited: 54, 123, 144. Bromley: 179. Brown, E. ; cited: 86. Buildings, cost of: 23, 53, 65, 96, 120, 142, 151, 156, 184-5, l8(>- Bulls, prices obtained: 81. Burn, R. S.; cited: 93 n., 163, 173, 178. Business qualities: 218 ff. Butter: see Dairying. Buxton, C. R.; cited: 128. Buying: 161, 188, 192. By-employments: 66, 88 f., 90, 92, 156 f., 215- Caird, Sir James; cited: 50, 55, 56, 58, 61, 68, 72, 103, 104. Cambridgeshire: 8, 23 n. 5, 85, 107, 149. Capital: 20, 21, 26, 44, 62, 71, 72, 74, 103, 120, 132 f., 159, 166-8, 179 f., 185, 201. intensive application of; 63, 181, 203, 211. security of tenants' capital; 138 f., 141. Capitalist agriculture: 66, 123 f., 184, 198, 212, 114, 221. Carrington, Lord: 94, 121, 115, 151. Catshill: 2 1 6. Cattle-breeding, economics of: 168-72. See also Cows, Pedigree Stock, Stock- farming. 244 Index Cattle-foods, artificial: 62, 64, 168-70. Celery: 106, 109. Chamber of Agriculture, the Central ; cited : 138- Chamberlain, Joseph: 94, 131, 146, 265. Channing, Sir F.; cited: 81, 96, 107, 109, no, U2, 123, 125, 131, 164 n. 4. Chaplin, Henry: 95. Charleton, W. L.: 194. Chatteris: 107. Cheney, E. J.: 149. Cheshire: 8, 90, in, 112, 174, 192. Child-Labour: 34, 172. Civil Service, the: 150. Classification of holdings: 3 f., 70, 88-93. Climate, effects of: 65, 67-9, 103, 205, 208-10. Cobden, Richard: 47ns. i & 5, 54 n. 3, 146. Ceilings, Jesse: 94, 95, 125, 132, 135, 136, 139, 146, 183. Comber, T. ; cited: 7 n. i, 21, 72. Commission of 1880-2: 101 f., 108-13, 185 n. i. Commission of 1894-7: 101 f., 107, 108-13, »57» !75> 179. *85 n. «, 195 n., 205. Commissioners (Small Holdings): 127 f., 148, 149, 152. Common-field System: 18 f., 27, 2811. Commons: 4, 18, 25, 26, 27, 28 n., 50, 202. Compensation : see Capital, security of tenants'. Competition : between the various units of holding ; 203-5, 1IQ f- for allotments; in. for farms ; 60 f., 102 f., 141. See also Foreign Competition. Compulsory hiring: 136-48, 150. Compulsory purchase: 129-31, 136 f., 140, 142, H3» i44-5°- Conservatism: 52, 82, 208 f. Conservative Party, the: 95, 121, 130, 131, 140, 142, 146, 150. Consolidation of Farms: 3, 16 f., 22 f., 26, 39 f., 102. See also Extension of Large Farm System. Consumers, profit by fall of prices: 58, 78 f., 2O2 f. , 2IO, 212, 213. Consumption : alleged inelasticity; 205-8. production for home; 4 f., 107 f. See also utider Markets, Standard of Comfort. Continental System, the: n, 44, 45 f., 60. Convertible husbandry: 83, 208. Co-operation : 62, 142 f., 150-2, 187-99, 208 f., 211, 216, 217, 220. Co-operative spirit, the: 198. Corn- Bounty: 10. Corn growing: 6, 10, 17, 21, «8 n., 60, 75-9, 124, 156-61, 168, 189 f. Advantages of large scale production in ; 3, 19 f., 27 f., 41, 61 f., 65, 70 f., '55-61, 181, 201, 204. Decline of; 75-9. Corn -growing, could. Extension of; 13-19, 48 f., 56, 19 f., 68, 200-202. on Small Holdings; 4-6, 17, 19, 53,64, 69 n., 107-10, in, ri2. Corn- Law Policy: see Protection. Com Laws, Abolition of: see Free Trade. Corn-prices: 8-21, 30 f., 39, 44, 46-8, 51, 55 f-» 75-8, 200-202. Cornwall: 22 n. 4, 112 n. 9. Cotswolds: 209. Cottages: 23, 26 n. 6, 36. Cottiers : see Labourers, Labourers' Holdings. County Councils: 126-53, 2'6- Cows: 14 n. 3, 24 f., 42 f., 48, 173. See also Dairying, ' Three Acres and a Cow.' Craigie, Major: 125. Cream: 79, 82. Crops, choice of: 107, 182. See also Rotation of Crops. Cumberland: 8, 50, 66, 69, 82, 214. Dairying: 5-7, 13, 17 f., 40, 62, 64, 60, 73, 79, 82-4, 89 f., 106, 108, not., 155, 172-8, 181, 183 n., 193-6, 203, 208 f., 219^ Dairymaids: 89, 172, 174, 177. David, Dr.; cited: 155, 177. Day-labour: see Labourers. Definition of small farmer: 4, 89. Definitions of holdings: 89-93, 99. Demand for Small Holdings: 67, 89, i26f., 141, 148 f., 152, 214-22. Denbighshire: 216. Denmark: 195, 198, 209, 210. Depopulation : see Emigration, Rural Exodus. Depression: see Agricultural Depression, Industrial Depression. Derbyshire: 8, 31, 90. Devon : 7 n. 3, »2 n. 4, 82, 98, 107 n. i, 1 10, 166, 172, 178, 182, 192. "Dirty" work: 172 f., 178. Distress, Agricultural : see Agricultural Depression. Distribution of Holdings : see Geographical Distribution. District Councils: 127, 128. Division of farms: 102, 113, 118, 119!".. 184 f., 203. Division of labour: 161, 177. Donaldson, James; cited: 5, 8, 18, 19 n., 20, 39. Dorset: 8, 82. Drainage: 20, 56, 59, 60 n. i. Durham: 8, no n. 6. Eastern counties, the: 67, 68, 77, 83 f., 103-5, no, 189, 191, 192. Economic forces: 20 f., 26, 28, 34, 51 f., 94, 95 f., 101-13, 126 f., 134, 143, H5. '50. '5*. i53-i86, 203, 211- I*. Index 245 Economic Policy: i, 40 f., 46, 48, 77 f., 105, in, 113. Economic theories: i, 2, 69-74, 153, 182 f. Eden, Sir F. M.: 12. Education: 20, 44, 155. Eggs: 5, 6n. i, 8, 13, 64, 79, 86, 179, 183 n., 197, 203, 119. Emigration: 38, 39. Enclosures: i8f., 24-7, 38 f., 44, 50, 54. "Engrossing": 16, 11, 16, 39 f. See also Consolidation of Farms. Entails: 118, 123. Epworth: i57n., isSn., i64n. Essex: 8, 25 n. i, 48, 68, 77, 83 f., 85, 98, 188, 208. Estate Management: 23, 53, 65, 185. See also Land-agents. Eversley, Lord; cited: 32, 65 n. 5, 96 n., 116 n. 2, 129, 130, 152. Evesham, Vale of: 85, 107, 163, 166. Evestan: 50 n. 4. Exeter: 7 n. 3, 194. Exmoor: 50. Exportation : of com ; 28 n. of pedigree stock ; 80 f. Extension of Large Farm System: 1,3, i6f., 21-44, 45, 50 f., 65 f., 68, 70 f., 102, 114 f., 2OI f. Extension of Small Holdings : 3, 55 f., 93-100, 101-13, 142 f., 203, 205-11, 315- See also Demand for Small Holdings. Factory-workers as Small Holders: 216, 217, 2i9f. Fair Rent: i4of. Fallow: i8f., 83. Feeding-crops: 15, 82, 106, 107 f., 109 n. i, 168-71, 208. See also Green crops, Root crops. Fitzhardinge, Lord : 193. Fixity of Tenure: i4of. Flintshire: in. Fodder: see Feeding-crops. Forcing: 84, 85, 104, 166, 220. Fordham, E. O.: 149. Foreign competition : 58, 77 f., 82, 124, 194 f., 208-10, 213. Foreign Trade: see Markets. Fox, A. Wilson ; cited : 47 n. 4, 52 n. 5, 87, "5- Foxes: 21 in. See also Sport. Free Sale : 1 40 f. Free Trade: 55-61, 75 f., 78, 168, 202, 205, 210, 213. Freehold Land Societies: 54 n. 3. Freeholders; see Yeomanry. Freeholders' Votes: 54 n. 3. Fruit - growing : see Market - Gardening, Orchards. Fruit-Growers League, the: 209. Fyffe, C. A.; cited: 102, 185. "Gentleman Farmers": 31, 91 f. Geographical distribution of farms: 67-9, 103 f., 189, 191 f. George, Henry: 145 Germany: 198, 214, 215. Giffen, Sir R. ; cited: 61. Gloucestershire: 8, 171, 192, 209. Goldsmith, Oliver; cited: 32 n. i, 38. Grading of goods: 194-7, 219. Graham, P. A. ; cited : 79, 83 n. 5, 84, 85 n. 4, 86, 87, 91, 188, 194 n., 196, 207, 209. Grass-land: see Pasture. Gray, H. L.: 33. Green crops: 58, 77, 160, 161, 169. Gurdon, John: 65 n. 2, 188. Haggard, H. Rider; cited: 86, no, 116, 157 n., 188. Hampden, Lord: 195. Hampshire: 64, 85, 98, 221. Harris, J. N.: 190, 195. Harrowby, Lord: 120. Harvest labour: 36, 89, 92, 122, 170. Harvests: iof., 15, 17, 28 n., 44, 49, 201. Hasbach, Dr. ; cited : 4, 8, 24, 25, 28 n., 32 f., 36 n. 7, 96 n. 2. Hay: 6n. 2, 89, 1701. Herd-book stock: see Pedigree Stock. Herefordshire: 90, 98, 112. Hertfordshire : 83, 167. Hesse: 198. Highlanders, emigration of: 39. Home Colonisation: 126, 150, 214-22. See also Demand for Small Holdings, Rural Exodus. Home market : see under Markets. Horses: 19 f., 80, 81, 156-8, 161, 162, 167. Housing: 23, 26 n. 6, 36, 185 n. Hunting: see Sport. Huntingdonshire: 28, in. Impey, F.; cited: 118, 221 f. Importation : of corn; n, 49, 57f., 75f., 202. of dairy produce, etc. ; 205-8. See also Foreign Competition. Industrial Depression : 45 f. , 52 f. Industrial Expansion: 33, 37, 45, 46, 57 f., 213. Intensivity of Capital: see under Capital. Intensivity of Labour: as price of independence; 35, 166. characteristic of Small Holders ; 6, 35, 63, 73, 74, 201 f., 203, 211. in distribution ; see Marketing, labour of management included; 220. social aspect; 211 f., 218, 220-2. required in dairying; 73, 155, 172-6, i77f., 181. „ market-gardening; 6, 73, 162 f., 166, 181, 201. ,, stock-farming; 6 f., 73, 171 ff., 180 f., 201. ,, on small holdings; 117, 215. 16 — t Index Jebb, L. ; cited: 150, 218. Johnson, A. H. : 32 f. Kautzsky, Karl; cited: 72. Kebbel, T. E. ; cited: nr, 153. Kent: 8, 33, 83, 84, 85, 90 n. 2, 98, 122, 159, 164, 179. Kent, N.; cited: 6, 7 n. 3, 12, 18, 19, 23, 36, 73. 183. King, Gregory: 15. Labour, intensive: see under Intensivity. Labour of Superintendence : see Manage- ment. Labour of Women: see Women's Work. Labour-market, the: 35-9, 52 f., 78, usf., 172 f., 111. Labourers: 3-5, 6, n, 35-8, 54, 73, 74, 89, 115-8, 125, r6r, 172 f., 178, 181, 2OI, 215, 2l8, 221, 222. Work of arable farms suited to ; 6, 74, 161, 201. See also Demand for Land, Pauperisa- tion, Proletarianisation, Standard of Comfort. Labourers' Friend Society: 52, 94, 117. Labourers' Holdings: 3-5, 14, 17, 18, 24 f., 36 f., 50, 116-8. See also Allotments. "Labouring Poor": n. Lancashire: 8, 33, 98. Land: demand for; 31 f. exhaustion of; 19 n. 5, 20 n. 6, 57. non-economic value of; 118-22, 123 f., 128 f., 132, 136, 143-6, 211. small parcels unobtainable; i28f., 151. sources of demand for ; see under Demand for Small Holdings. Land-agents: 121 f., 123, 129, 149, 185. See also Estates, cost of administration. Land Club League, the: 148. Land Laws: 36, 41, 118, 123. Land Monopoly: 26, 29, 95, 123, 124. Land-ownership, Problem of: 31 f., 66 f., 118-24, 136. See also Land, non-economic value of, and Proprietorship. Land Nationalisation Society: 146 n. Land Reform movement : 94, 121, 130, 145. Land Restoration League: 146 n. Land Tax Assessments : 32 f. Landlords: 14, 25, 26, 27, 29, 36, 41, 51 f., 65, 83, 95, iorf., 119-21, 136-40, 141 f., 183 f., 203. dislike of allotments; 36, 43 f., 53, 149. provide allotments ; 36, 43 f., 54, 94. See also Enclosures, Estates, Land- monopoly, Rents. Lander, W. H.; cited: 157. Large Farm System, extension of: see Ex- tension. Law of Diminishing Returns: 200, 201. Law of Increasing Returns : 72, 96, 204. Lawes, J. B.: 57. Lawry, J. W.; cited: 101, 179, 183. Lawson, W.: 188. Lefevre, Geo. Shaw: see Eversley, Lord. Legislative Action: 36, 41, 94 f.« 125-53, 203. Leicester: 217. Leicestershire: 28, 112, 151 n. 2. Liberal Party, the: 94, 114, 118, 126, 131, 136, 146, 150. Lincolnshire: 6, 8, 17, 27, 31, 68, 77, 85, non. 6, 127, 129, 142, 150 f., i57n., 164. Lloyd-Baker, G. E.; cited: 87, 171, 208. London: 7, 8, 37 f., 85, 116, 191, 195 n. Loram, E. T. : 172, 194. Low, David; cited: 71. Lynn: 27 n. Machinery: 20, 57, 62, 64, 65 n. i, 74, 96, 155. iSSHSi. I(53» ^7, 170 f-» 176 f., 182, 189, 193 f., 201, 204, 215, 219 f. Malthus, T. R. : 42. Management, work of: 6, 89 f., 92, 161, 163, 171, 218-21. Manchester: 116. Manufactures: see Industrial Expansion. Manures: 19, 56 f., 59 f., 62, 160 f., 166, 167. Market Conditions: 13, 17, 48 f., 74 f., 200-205. determine agricultural production; 47, 72, 86, 200-205, 211-13. Market-Gardeners' Compensation Act : 139^ Market- Gardening: 5, 6, 8, 13, 30, 55, 66, 79, 84 f., 90, 106-12, 162-8, 183 n., 196 f., 207 f., 209", 219, 220, 221 f. advantage of small-scale production in; 6, 4°. 55. 64, 73, 106-9, 181, 220. Marketing: 7, 157, 162, 165 n., 167, 174 f., 182, 194-7, 218 f. Markets: 7 f., 45 f., 74-9, 162, 164 f., 174 f., 177, 194, 216, 218. Home market, the; 17 f., 46 f., 50, 57 t., 82, 200-204, 210, 212 f. Labour-market, the; see under Labour. Marshall, W. ; cited: 13, 20, -29, 30, 70, 72 f. Marx, Karl; cited: 70, 72. Matthews, A. T.; cited: 80, 81, 82. Means of Communication : 7 f., 37 f., 55, 57, 75 f., 119, 162, 164, i?4f., 195-7. 202 f., 219. Meat: 5, 6 n. i, 8, 13, 47, 48 f., 57, 58, 63, 76, 79 f., 82, 168, 201, 202, 203, 210, 212. Mechi, J. J. : 57. Middlemen: 159 f., 164 f., 168 n., 189, 192, 194. Middlesex: 98. Milk: 5, 6, 58, 640. 3, 79, 82, 207. See also Dairying. Milking: 89, 172 f., 177. Mill, J. S.; cited: 73 f., 94. Index 247 Mixed husbandry: 15, 57-63, 86, 168, 181, 101. Monmouthshire : 112. Mortgages: 33, 51, 109. Mountain land: 69, 169. Nail-makers: 216. Natural economy: see under Consumption. Netherby: 50. Nettles, used for food: 47. Newark: 157 n., 194. Newdigate: 151. Norfolk : 8, 10, 27, 30, 65 n. 3, 68, 77, 83, no, no, 127, 142, 151, 189, 208. Northamptonshire: 28, 98. Northumberland: 91 f. Nottinghamshire: 27, 98, 151 n., 157 n. Onslow, Lord: 125. Orchards: 14, 50 n. 4, 84, 85, 112, 162, 163, 165, 166, 209. Organisation, work of: see Management. Ownership: see Proprietorship. Oxen: 19. Oxfordshire : 14 n. 5, 33. Packing: 196, 219. Parish Councils: 127, 128. Park Street: 167. Parker, Sir G. : 150 n. i. Parliament: 41, 146, 211. Pamdon: 25 n. Pasture: 27 f., 82 f., 120, 152. conversion to arable; 14 f., 22, 27, 48 f., 50, 68. Pasture-districts: 63, 68 f., 103-5, 110-12, 191. Pasture-farming, scientific methods applied: 48 f., 79-84, 86, 168-71, 176 f., 193 f., 208 f., 219 f. See also Stock-farming. Pauperisation: 12, 340. 4, 36, 43, 52. Peace conditions : 45 f., 48, 212 f. Peas, labourers eat raw: 13. Peasantry: 3, 4, 16 f., 20, 24-44, 74, 132, 222. See also Proprietorship. Pedigree stock: 80 f., i?9f. Pensaxt: 157 n. Pigs: 5» 6, 7. 8» i3» 80 f., 106, 108, 178, 183 n. Ploughing, expensive on small holdings: 19, 53, 62, 156-8, 169. Plough-land: see Arable land. Poor Law: see Pauperisation. Population : effect of increase in i8th century; 8, u, 28 n., 200 f. effect of increase in i9th century ; 55, 202. percentage occupied in agriculture; 37. Potatoes: 85, 89, 106, 107, 109, 166-8, 181. Poultry-keeping: 5, 6, 8, 9, 13, 18, 19, 79, 86, 108, 157, 178 f., 183 n., 203, 209 f., 211 n., 220. Poultry-keeping, contd. advantage of small-scale production in ; 64, 106 f., 112, 181. Poultry Organisation Society, the: 86, 197. Pratt, E. A.; cited: 142, 143, 194 n., 198 n., 217, 218, 219, 220, 221. Price, Dr; cited: 4711.3, 29, 38 n. 4, 41, 94- Prices: see Market Conditions, Statistics, Tables. Primogeniture: 109, 118, 123. Pringle, Andrew ; cited : 29. Pringle, R. H.; cited: 83, 92, 109. Production : combination of various branches; 182. determines unit of holding ; 88, 155, 183, 200, 203. Proletarianisation : 24, 34-7, 41 f., 44, 116. Proprietorship, controversy regarding: 74, 118, 131-7, 140, 15°. 15'- Protection, policy of : 46 f. , 48, 50, 54, 56, 75f.» ?8, 201 f. Prothero, R. E.; cited: 4, 19, 34, 62. Purchasing-power of Wages: 9, u, 35 f., 58, 78 f., 201. Pusey, P.: 57. Quarterly Review, the; cited: 145. Queniborough : 25 n. 5. Radical Party, the: 94, 95, 132, 146. Rae, Dr; cited: 3, 4, 33. Railway construction : 52 n. 6. Railway tariffs: 174 f., 195-7- Read, C. S.; cited: 102, in, 156, 166, 175, 179, 182, 189. Reformers : see Social Policy. Rent: 9, ion., 21-22, 23, 25, 31, 49, 53, 60 f., 65, 77, 85, 101 f., 119, 137 ff., 177 f., 185. Repairs, cost of: see Buildings, cost of. Reports : see Commissions, Small Holdings Committees. Retail prices, obtained by small holders: 165. Rew, R. H.; cited: 80, 82, 86, 97 n., 107 n., 210. Riots: 39. Robertson, T. ; cited : 19 n. 7, 67, 68, 103, 104. Rogers, J. D.; cited: 33 n. 4. Root-crops, 5, 15, 19, 20, 48, 77, 83, 107, 160, 169. Rotation of crops: 15, 19, 20, 48, 61, 77, 160, 168, 202. Royal Agricultural Society : 56 f. Rural exodus : of 1 8th century: 37-9- of igth century: 52 f., 78, 95, 114-18, 172 f., 187, 203, 212, 217. Salisbury, Lord; cited: 95, 130. Samuel, H.; cited: 106, 114, 117, 130. Schleswig-Holstein : 198. 248 Index Scottish farmers : 48 n. 4, 83 f., 92, 208. Seasons: see Harvests. Selkirk, Earl of; cited: it, 39. Shaw, Professor ; cited : 1 78. Sheep-farming: 3, 6, 58, 63, 69, 80, 106, 169. Sheldon, Professor ; cited : 1 74. Shooting: see Sport. Shropshire: 8, 98, 157, 171. Sinclair, Sir John ; cited : 20, 30, 32, 34, 42 f., 70, 71, 72, 94. Small Holders, types of: see under Demand. Small Holdings, revival of : see Extension of Small Holdings. Small Holdings Act, 1907 : 95, 124, 125, 126, 127 f., 136-53, 215 f. Small Holdings and Allotments Act, 1892 : 05, 125, 126-33, 143. Small Holdings Associations : see Co-opera- tion. Small Holdings Committee, 1889 : 94, 95, 96, 106, 183 n., 185 n., 209. Small Holdings Committee, 1905-6: 91 n., 96 n. 2, 98, 99, in, 121 n., 125 f., 127, 128, 130, 131, 133, i34f., 136, 140, 142, 183 n., 185 n., 215 f., 217, 219. Smith, H. H. ; cited: 133. Social Policy: i, 2, 4, 34-6, 41 f., 51 f., 72-4, 94 f., 153, 212 f., 214-22. Societies: 54 n. 3, 56 f., 86, 146 n., 190 f., 195, 197, 210. See also Co-operation. Soil, special qualities of: 65, 67-9, 83, 90, 103, 205, 208-10. Somerset: 192. Somerville, Professor; cited: 57. South-eastern district : 83. Southampton, district surrounding: 107. Spade-cultivation: 53, 162 f., 166, 167. Spalding: 150. Sport: 31, n8f., 120, 122, 129, 136, 145, 211 n. Staffordshire: 98. Standard of comfort: 5, 9, 11-13, 3r» 35» 46-8, 58, 78 f., 86, 201-3. Starvation : 25, 47 f. State, the : see Legislative Action. "Statesman": 31, 69 n. Statistics, criticised : 99. Statistics : Acreage allotted to labourers on enclosure ; M- Agricultural labourers, decrease in number of, 1851-1901; 115. Cattle, increase in number kept, 1876- 1909; 80. Changes in unit of holding, 1885-1895; „ 97- Co-operative associations; 190 n., 191. Farmers' relatives assisting in work ; 117. Holdings, geographical distribution of; 68 n. 5. Holdings of the various classes ; 98 f. Horses required per unit of holding ; 157, 158 n. Statistics, contd. Imported produce of petite culture, value of ; 206 f. Market-gardens, etc., 1878-1909; 84 f. Pedigree stock, value of; 81. Permanent pasture, 1876-1909; 79 f. Poultry-keeping, 1885-1902; 86. Small Holdings and Allotments Acts, land acquired under; 1887-1902 : 130. 1892-1902: 126. 1907-1910: 147 f. See also Tables. Steam-dairies: 172, 193 f. Steam-ploughing: 62, 64, 159. Sterilisation of milk : 194. Stock-farming: 3, 5, 6, 13, 15, i?f., 27, 30 f., 48 f., 55-9, 6 1 f., 64, 68 f., 76 f., 79-84, 108-13, 168-80, 183 n., 186, J9of., 197, 201, 203, 208, 2iof. Advantages of large-scale production in ; 169 f., i76f., i79f., 181. Advantages of small-scale production in ; 55. 73» I0<5» J7i f-» i8of., 1830. On arable holdings; 105 f., 109 f., 160, 168 f., 181, 208 f. See also under Pasture. Straw: 107. Strawberry-growing: 79, 107, 164, 222. Sub-letting: 177. Suffolk: 8, 14 n. 3, 27, 48, 68, 77, no, 208. Superintendence : see Management. Surrey: 98, 151, 152. Sussex: 86, 98, 112, 211 n. Sutton, M. J. ; cited: 208. Swaffham : 27 n. Switzerland: 198. Tables: Animals kept on the various units; 106. Area under corn and green crops, 1881- 1909; 77. Export of pedigree stock, 1876-1900; 81. Geographical distribution of Holdings ; 103, 104, 105. Holdings of the various classes, 1870- 1885; 66. Holdings of the various classes, 1880-95; Holdings of the various classes in 1895 ; Holdings of the various classes, 1895- 1909; 97. Horses kept per unit of holding; 158. Imports of Butter, Cheese and Condensed Milk, 1886-1909; 206. Imports of Fruit, Poultry and Eggs, 1892-1909; 207. Prices of machines of varying capacity ; 170. Prices of separators of various capacities ; 176. Wages and Prices, 1883-1902; 78. Wheat and meat prices, 1877-1902; 76. Index 249 Tariffs, foreign : 46, 75, 79 f. Taylor, James : 54 n. 3. Technique: see Agricultural Science. Telephones : 119. Tenancy: see Proprietorship. Tenants, security of Capital: i^Sf., 141. Thaer, Albrecht; cited: i.sn. 7, 30, 70. Thonger, Professor; cited: 173. Thornton, W. T. ; cited: 53, 55. "Three Acres and a Cow": 43, 90, 118. "Three F's," the: 140 f., 150. Three-field System, the: 15, 18, 168. Threshing-machines: son. 2, 62, 159 f., 189. Tollemache, Lord: 94. Tonbridge: 90 n. 2, 159 n. Tooke, T. ; cited: 8 n. 12, 9 ns., 10 f., 46 n. 5. Town-life, attraction of: 37, 38, 116, 214. Towns: 67, 97 f., 119. As a market; 53, 84, 85, 216. Townsmen as Small Holders: 215-22. Toynbee, Arnold: 34 n. 2. Transport, cost of : 57, 164, 174 f., 195-7- See also Means of Communication. Tremenhere, — ; citetl : 64, 65, 69. "Trifles": 73. Turnips: 5, 15, 19, 20, 77, 83, 107, 160, 169. Vegetables: 5, 6, 17, 20, 79, 203, 209. See also Market-Gardening. Village communities: 188 n. 4, 198. Voelcker, A. : 57. Wages: 5, 9, ri f., 35 f., 41, 46, 57 f., 6?» 78, 172 f., 201, 203. See also Standard of Comfort. Wages-Scales: 12. Wales: 98, 191. Wantage, Lord: 94, 151. War conditions: 10, u, 15, 17, 18, 44, 46 f., 2OI f., 21) f. Warwickshire: «8, 191, 192. Water-supply: 120. Wealth, national: 8, 55, 66, 82. Wenlock, Lord: in. Wensleydale: i94n. Western counties, the : 68 f., 103-5, IIO» '9'» 192. Westmorland: 8, 29, 62, 66, 69, 169, 174, 192. Wheat: see Bread, Corn. Wheatley, — : 38. Whitley,'j. H.: 151. Wilkins, Mrs; cited: 150, 218. Williams, George: 216. Wiltshire: 2in. i, 99, 216. Winchilsea, Earl of: 25 n. i, 370.1, 43. Winfrey, R. ; cited: 117, 142, 150 f. Women's Work : 7 n. 3, 18, 34, 89 f., 165 n., i?«. '73. '74. '75. »?8f., '82, 197. Wool-prices: 63. Worcestershire: 62, 85, 98. 127, 191, 192, 216. Worthing: 220. Wrightson, J.; cited: 82. Yeomanry: 4, 26 f., 28-35, 5f«<>9» '°9» '34. 314. Yerburgh, R. A.; cited: 87, 125, 190, 212 f. Yorkshire: 7, 14 n. 4, 86 n. 3, 98, 102, "•• 173. 193- Young, Arthur; cited: 5, 6, 8 n. 10, 10, 12, 14, 16, 17, 19, 20, 21, it n. a, 75 n., 27, 28 n., 32, 35, 37 f., 41, 47, 68, 69-71, 88, 94, 135, 156. CAMBRIDGE: PRINTED BY JOHN CLAY, M.A. AT THE UNIVERSITY PRESS. .* GO fe f» U E i •H rH fl rH -O « 5 H UNIVERSITY OF TORONTO LIBRARY Do not Acme Library Card Pocket Under Pat. " Ref. Index File." Made \sj LIBRARY