Skip to main content

Full text of "Economic impacts of commercial applications of biotechnology in field-crop production"

See other formats


UNIVERSITY  OF 

ILLINOIS  LIBRARY 

AT  URBANA-CHAMPAIGN 

AGRICULTURE 


NOnCE  Hetum  or  renew  all  Ubrwy  MalerWsl  The  Minimum  F««  «or 

each  Lost  Book  is  $50.00. 

The  person  charging  this  material  is  responsible  for 

its  return  to  the  library  from  which  it  was  withdrawn 

on  or  before  the  Latest  Date  stamped  below. 

Theft,  mutilation,  and  underlining  of  book,  are  reasons  for  diseip«- 

nary  action  and  may  result  in  dismissal  from  the  University. 

To  renew  call  Telephone  Center,  333-8400 


UNIVERSITY    OF    ILLINOIS    LIBRARY    AT    URBANA-CHAMPAIGN 


L161—  O-1096 


AU6  1  2  1992 

«WCULTURE  LIWAKY 


r^.^?^^^ 


HUNG** 


Economic  Impacts  of 
Commercial  Applications 
of  Biotechnology  in 
Field-Crop  Production 


Wojciech  ].  Florkowski 
and  Lowell  D.  Hill 


Bulletin  799 

University  of  Illinois  at  Urbana-Champaign 

College  of  Agriculture 

Agricultural  Experiment  Station 


^.  N  •  ^V'-\^>"  -:•  •''  -^.. 
'^^\-\H'!'1-^V-^^'- 


.-  --.  - 


AUTHORS:  Wojciech  J.  Florkowski  is  an  assistant  professor  of  agricultural  economics  at 
the  University  of  Georgia  and  Georgia  Experiment  Station,  Griffin,  Georgia.  Lowell  D. 
Hill  is  the  L.J.  Norton  Professor  of  Agricultural  Marketing  in  the  Department  of 
Agricultural  Economics  at  the  University  of  Illinois  at  Urbana-Champaign,  Urbana, 
Illinois. 


Editor:  Mary  E.  Theis 
Designer:  Krista  Sunderland 

The  Illinois  Agricultural  Experiment  Station  provides  equal  opportunities  in  programs  and  employment. 


U.S.  scientific  leaders  in  the  development 
of  agricultural  biotechnology  can  contrib- 
ute to  the  economic  growth  of  many  coun- 
tries by  commercializing  plant  cultivars  with 
improved  genetic  characteristics.  In  the  face 
of  limited  resources  and  the  high  cost  of 
research,  the  undesirable  effects  of  past 
adoptions  of  technology  have  made  the 
public  and  research  community  more  aware 
of  the  importance  of  evaluating  economic 
impacts  before  adopting  a  technology.  Lack 
of  information  about  the  potential  effects 
of  biotechnology  has  led  to  a  discussion  of 
its  environmental  hazards  (Brill),  social  is- 
sues (like  those  described  by  Buttel),  and 
patenting  of  altered  cultivars  (Schmid).  Bio- 
technology has  also  been  the  focus  of 
several  agricultural  economists  (Butler; 
Sundquist  et  al;  Lu;  Harl;  Hill  et  al;  Offut 
and  Kuchler;  Kalter  and  Tauer;  Hueth  and 
Just). 

The  U.S.  Department  of  Agriculture  (USDA) 
and  the  Office  of  Technology  Assessment 
of  the  U.S.  Congress  have  conducted  stud- 
ies on  the  impacts  of  agricultural  biotech- 
nology as  well  as  other  modern  technolo- 
gies. But  most  of  these  studies  have  avoided 
the  issues  of  distributional  welfare  effects 
as  the  technologies  have  been  commer- 
cially adopted. 

Analysts  of  economic  and  social  conse- 
quences have  often  relied  on  qualitative 
evaluation  without  quantifying  the  results. 
Any  attempt  to  quantify  something  so  com- 
plex as  the  welfare  effects  of  adopting  a 
technology  must  incorporate  numerous 
simplifying  assumptions  and  be  limited  to 
partial  equilibrium  analysis.  Useful  insights 
into  relationships  among  the  important 
variables  can  be  obtained  by  quantifying 
at  least  first-order  consequences  of  change. 

With  the  use  of  static  analysis,  this  man- 
uscript provides  estimates  of  the  welfare 
changes  associated  with  commercialization 
of  twelve  alternative  plant  biotechnologies. 
Welfare  is  measured  by  consumer  and  pro- 
ducer surpluses.  The  analysis  gives  infor- 
mation about  the  potential  regional  real- 
location  of  agricultural  land  and  about 
welfare  gains  to  consumers.  The  models 
used  in  the  analysis  demonstrate  long- 


term,  aggregate  effects  of  each  new  tech- 
nology, assuming  full  adoption.  Impacts  of 
each  technology  are  examined  indepen- 
dently of  the  other  eleven;  no  simultaneous 
adoption  of  two  or  more  technologies  was 
allowed  in  the  model. 

Description  of  Selected 
Alternative  Biotechnologies 

Symbiotic  Changes.  This  biotechnological 
alternative  focuses  on  improving  the  ability 
of  plants  to  obtain  nitrogen  from  the  soil. 
Nitrogen  fixation  technology  would  enable 
corn  and  other  plants  to  fix  nitrogen  on 
their  roots  much  as  the  soybean  plant  does 
now.  This  symbiotic  technology  would  be 
of  great  importance  to  farmers  because 
nitrogen  fertilizer  represents  a  significant 
cost  and  because  the  lack  of  supply  in 
many  countries  prohibits  use  of  fertilizer 
at  the  optimum  levels. 

New  Rhizobia  Strains.  Genetic  changes  in 
rhizobia,  bacterial  species  capable  of  fixing 
nitrogen,  are  also  receiving  considerable 
attention.  The  symbiotic  relationship  be- 
tween rhizobia  and  legume  crops  is  rec- 
ognized as  having  significant  economic  im- 
portance in  agriculture  and  the  cost  of  food 
production.  Developing  new  strains  of  rhi- 
zobia that  will  be  effective  on  crops  other 
than  legumes  could  extend  this  beneficial 
relationship  to  other  crops.  These  rhizobia 
may  also  be  altered  to  increase  the  amount 
of  nitrogen  fixed  in  the  symbiotic  relation- 
ship currently  found  in  most  legume  crops. 

Altered  Protein  Content.  Biotechnology  can 
alter  the  chemical  composition  of  grains. 
Protein  content  and  quality,  in  terms  of 
amino  acid  balance,  are  of  special  impor- 
tance. In  countries  suffering  from  protein 
deficiency,  increased  protein  would  directly 
improve  nutritional  levels.  Higher  protein 
grains  could  also  reduce  the  cost  of  pro- 
duction for  livestock  where  supplemental 
protein  is  now  required. 

New  Resistant  Varieties.  Besides  directly  de- 
stroying the  plant,  pests  can  indirectly  cause 
plant  loss  by  creating  an  environment  con- 
ducive to  other  diseases.  Resistant  varieties 


of  plants  can  be  developed  by  directing 
genetic  changes.  The  southern  corn  leaf 
blight  is  one  example  of  how  genetic  dif- 
ferences have  altered  the  impact  of  a  dis- 
ease. Developing  corn  plants  resistant  to 
aspergillus  flavis  is  also  a  high  research 
priority  in  many  countries. 

Frost  Tolerance.  Frost  damage  to  crops  fre- 
quently lowers  the  yield  or  totally  destroys 
crops  in  many  parts  of  the  world.  Some 
plants  are  highly  susceptible,  others  quite 
tolerant  to  cold  temperatures  including 
frost.  Genetic  manipulation  could  increase 
the  resistance  of  important  crops  to  the 
danger  of  occasional  frost. 

Herbicide  Tolerance.  Increased  herbicide  tol- 
erance would  increase  crop  yields  and  the 
value  of  a  crop  where  treatment  for  pests, 
diseases,  or  weeds  harms  the  protected 
crop.  Genetic  changes  could  neutralize  the 
impact  of  herbicide  residues  in  the  soil. 
Significant  commercial  progress  has  been 
made  on  this  technology  in  recent  years. 

Heat  Tolerance.  Heat  stress  significantly 
lowers  the  yields  of  many  crops.  In  some 
cases,  it  precludes  the  cultivation  of  some 
feed  and  food  cereals  in  regions  where 
they  are  needed.  The  global  warming  trend 
may  also  increase  the  interest  in  heat  tol- 
erance for  many  crops  now  grown  in  tem- 
perate regions.  Developing  varieties  that 
are  resistant  to  heat  is  one  of  the  objectives 
of  genetic  manipulation. 

Plant  Growth  Regulators  (PGRs).  These  reg- 
ulators stimulate  or  retard  plant  growth. 
Some  growth  regulators  are  now  in  com- 
mercial operation.  For  example,  wheat  may 
be  sprayed  to  control  plant  growth  and 
prevent  lodging.  Future  developments  in 
biotechnology  may  widen  the  array  of  uses 
and  plants  for  which  PGRs  are  effective. 


Ice-Retarding  Bacteria.  Crop  production  can 
be  influenced  not  only  by  genetic  changes 
in  the  plants  but  also  by  genetic  changes 
in  the  microorganisms  associated  with  the 
plants.  Ice-retarding  bacteria,  one  such  ex- 
ample, has  been  chosen  for  analysis  in  this 
study  because  it  has  been  developed  to  the 
point  of  experimental  application.  Presence 
of  these  microorganisms  prevent  damage 
to  crops  from  low  temperatures  of  sur- 
rounding air. 

The  Model 

Assuming  that  the  agricultural  sector  op- 
erates under  conditions  of  perfect  compe- 
tition, by  maximizing  the  sum  of  consumer 
and  producer  surpluses  incorporated  in  an 
objective  function,  we  can  estimate  changes 
in  welfare  after  the  use  of  selected  agri- 
cultural biotechnologies.  This  procedure 
was  developed  by  Samuelson  and  made 
operational  by  Takayama  and  Judge 
through  application  of  quadratic  program- 
ming (QP).  As  an  alternative  to  QP,  Duloy 
and  Norton  suggested  a  linear-program- 
ming (LP)  algorithm  with  grid  linearization. 
This  method  allows  an  analysis  of  both 
separable  and  nonseparable  demand  func- 
tions and  has  been  recommended  for  ag- 
ricultural sector  analysis  (McCarl  and 
Spreen).  Taylor  et  al.  applied  this  grid 
linearization  to  separable  demand  func- 
tions. In  case  of  nonseparable  demand 
functions,  the  price  is  expressed  as  a  func- 
tion of  parameters  of  substitutes'  demand 
functions.  An  integral  incorporated  into  the 
objective  function  of  the  model  used  to 
estimate  welfare  and  distribution  effects  of 
technology  adoption  for  a  two-commodity, 
two-market  case  is: 


=  /Q,c-(flc. 
\ 


bcst) 


bce) 


/     (bscd  +  bm)  (b«  +  bx)     \ 
\1  -  ((&„,  +  &„)  (bcd  +  bct))J 


where  subscript  c  refers  to  one  commodity, 
for  example,  corn;  subscript  s  refers  to 
another  commodity,  for  example,  sorghum; 
d  indicates  the  domestic  market,  e  the 
export  market;  Q,  is  the  total  quantity  of 
the  domestic  and  export  market;  P  is  the 
price  of  each  commodity.  The  equation 
becomes  a  part  of  an  integral  measuring 
the  area  under  the  demand  function  for 
commodity  c,  with  Q,s  as  an  argument.  A 
similar  derivation  procedure  was  followed 
in  specifying  the  objective  function  used 
in  this  study  (Florkowski). 

Future  characteristics  of  agricultural  bio- 
technologies, yield,  and  the  use  of  fertilizer 
and  pesticides,  must  be  incorporated  into 
a  model  in  order  to  provide  a  reliable 
solution.  With  information  about  the  di- 
rection of  changes  in  input  use  from  an 
international  survey  (Florkowski  and  Hill), 
we  assumed,  after  consulting  agronomists, 
that  the  size  of  increase  or  decrease  in  a 
specific  input  use  would  amount  to  10 
percent  of  its  cost.  The  international  survey 
also  provided  estimates  of  expected  yield 
changes  (Table  1).  Twelve  of  the  twenty 
technologies  included  in  the  survey  were 
included  in  the  analytical  model.  The  prin- 
cipal criterion  for  selection  was  the  prob- 
ability of  rapid  commercial  adoption  as- 
signed by  survey  respondents.  Other 
selection  criteria  included  possible  future 
changes  in  input  use  induced  by  biotech- 
nologies, expected  yield  changes,  goals  of 
plant-breeding  programs,  and  the  availa- 
bility of  the  necessary  data  for  specifying 
a  model.  This  study  considered  only  the 
impact  of  genetic  improvement  through 
biotechnology  and  the  minimum  changes 
in  input  use.  Other  factors  have  been  omit- 
ted, such  as  machinery  that  decreases  soil 
compaction  and  increased  yields  from 
higher  concentrations  of  atmospheric  car- 
bon dioxide  or  improved  management. 

The  formulated  benchmark  model  used 
statistics  published  in  the  final  version  of 
the  1982  Federal  Enterprise  Data  System 
(FEDS)  Budgets  on  the  cost  and  quantities 
of  inputs  applied  per  acre  for  nine  row 
crops:  barley,  corn,  cotton,  oats,  peanuts, 
rice,  sorghum,  soybeans,  and  wheat.  In 


order  to  arrive  at  the  cost  of  production  at 
the  regional  level,  the  production  costs 
reported  for  states  were  weighted  by  the 
state's  share  in  acreage  planted  of  a  crop 
in  a  given  region  in  1982. 

The  costs  used  in  the  model,  which  are 
variable  cost  categories  reported  by  budget 
data  and  fixed  costs,  include  the  cost  of 
machinery,  tractors,  and  general  farm  over- 
head. The  cost  of  share  rent  was  excluded 
because  it  represents  a  part  of  the  calcu- 
lated consumer  and  producer  surpluses. 

This  study  uses  Soil  Conservation  Service 
(SCS)  data  on  yield  adjustment  for  different 
land  classes  compiled  in  1974  (USDA,  1975) 
and  used  in  studies  by  Nicol  and  by  Taylor 
and  Frohberg.  Data  on  the  amount  of  land 
available  in  different  quality  classes  were 
obtained  from  the  USDA  Natural  Resource 
Inventory.  Yields  in  the  model  were  cal- 
culated as  simple  averages  of  yields  re- 
ported by  the  SCS  and  adjusted  by  land 
class. 

The  averages  were  further  adjusted  for 
genetic  yield  improvement  between  1974 
and  1982  in  order  to  make  the  yield  data 
correspond  to  1982  cost  estimates.  The  size 
of  the  yield  increase  from  genetic  gain  was 
obtained  through  field  tests  (Miller  and 
Kebede;  Meredith  and  Bridge)  or  through 
interviews  with  experts  (Hymowitz;  Lam- 
bert). In  the  case  of  cotton  and  peanuts, 
no  field  test  data  were  available,  so  we 
adjusted  yields  by  calculating  a  percentage 
increase  using  the  difference  between 
weighted  average  yields  for  the  early  1970s 
and  1980s.  We  calculated  weights  as  a 
percentage  share  of  the  total  regional  har- 
vested acreage  for  each  state.  The  yield  of 
rice  in  the  benchmark  model  remained 
unchanged  because  the  comparison  of  av- 
erages between  the  two  periods  did  not 
show  significant  differences.  We  assumed 
that  the  yield  of  oats  and  barley  increased 
by  0.3  percent  annually  because  of  genetic 
improvement.  For  crops  not  explicitly  in- 
cluded in  the  model,  an  estimate  of  total 
land  area  allocated  to  these  crops  was 
withdrawn  from  the  total  land  available  in 
the  model  for  crop  production. 


Table  1.  Expected  Percentage  Changes  in  Yield  from  Application  of  Selected  Biotechnologies 


Technology 


Corn 


Rice 


Sorghum        Soybeans          Wheat 


percent 

Symbiotic' 

-4 

-3 

-8 

7 

-2 

New  rhizobia  strainsb 

4 

1 

-2 

12 

0 

Altered  protein0 

-3 

-5 

-8 

1 

-4 

Virus-resistant11 

8 

9 

9 

7 

9 

Bacteria-resistantd 

8 

6 

5 

10 

6 

Fungus-resistantd 

10 

12 

7 

12 

7 

Insect-resistant5 

10 

10 

10 

8 

11 

Frost-tolerant' 

6 

9 

8 

7 

8 

Herbicide-tolerant8 

4 

9 

5 

10 

6 

Heat-tolerant" 

5 

5 

7 

12 

8 

Plant  growth  regulator' 

12 

13 

3 

12 

5 

Ice-retarding  bacteria' 

5 

6 

6 

6 

4 

'Biotechnology  altering  a  plant  in  order  to  induce  a  symbiosis  between  a  plant  and  nitrogen-fixing  bacteria. 

bGenetically  altered  rhizobia  strains  that  through  symbiotic  association  with  a  plant  increase  the  amount  of  nitrogen 

available  to  a  plant. 

'Biotechnology  increasing  the  content  of  digestible  protein  in  kernels. 

dVirus-resistant,  bacteria-resistant,  and  fungus-resistant  plants  developed  through  biotechnology  are  plants  that  are 

resistant  to  economically  important  diseases  caused  by  viruses,  bacteria,  or  fungi. 

Tlants  resistant  to  insect  damage. 

'Plants  tolerating  below  freezing  temperatures  through  their  internal  mechanism. 

8Plants  tolerating  a  high  level  of  herbicide  spray. 

hPlants  that  have  a  high  tolerance  for  extreme  temperatures  during  a  growing  season. 

'Plants  responding  to  plant  growth  regulators  applied  during  a  growing  season  by  increased  yields. 

'Genetically  altered  bacteria  that  when  sprayed  on  frost-sensitive  plants  delay  ice  crystal  formation,  preventing  frost 

damage. 


Individual  crops,  crop  mixes  (McCarl),  and 
rotations  used  in  the  benchmark  model 
were  based  on  USDA  agricultural  statistics 
for  the  last  5  to  10  years,  on  the  graphic 
summary  of  the  location  of  crop  production 
from  the  latest  U.S.  census  of  agriculture, 
on  FEDS  Budgets,  and  on  personal  inter- 
views with  agricultural  experts  from  a 
number  of  states.  Crop  mixes  were  fixed 
for  each  region,  and  the  share  of  total  acres 
allocated  to  each  crop  in  any  given  mix 
was  based  on  the  historical  data  provided 
by  various  sources.  The  acreage  of  each 
crop  within  the  crop  mix  was  constrained 


by  that  crop's  share  of  total  acreage  and 
by  the  total  acreage  of  cropland  available. 
Individual  crops  not  included  in  a  crop  mix 
were  constrained  only  by  the  available 
acreage  of  cropland  in  the  region. 


Benchmark  Model  Solution 
and  Validation 

A  benchmark  model  for  ten  regions  of  the 
United  States  including  nonirrigated  and 
irrigated  land  is  presented  below. 


MAX  s  =  2  D.  -  2  2  2  c^*  -22 


2 

j 


MAX  S  =  Maximize  the  sum  of  the  consumer  and  producer  surpluses,  subject  to  the 
following  constraints: 


1.  Land  constraint 

2  Akmi  <  14  —   total  nonirrigated  land;  for  all  k,  m,  j 
/ 
2  Aki  <  Lf  —   total  irrigated  land;  for  all  k,  i,  j 

i 

2.  Commodity  balance 

222  YL/.^  +222  n.^  -  2  Qs  ^  o  for aii « 

m          /  t  I  >  *  p 

3.  Constraints  on  steps  for  area  under  the  demand  function  for  each  commodity 

2  ZE  <  1.0  for  all  H 

p 

4.  Demand-supply  balance 

2  Q"n  ^  Tn  for  all  n 

P 

5.  Constraints  on  acreage  allocated  to  each  crop 
2  A'mln  <  2  ak  Lkm  for  all  k,  j,  n;  0  <  a  <  \ 

m  m 

2  Al,n  <  2  *>"  L?  for  all  k,  j,  n;  0  <  b  <  I 

i  i 

where 

a        is  a  coefficient  allocating  a  proportion  of  the  total  available  nonirrigated 

land  class  to  production  of  a  crop  under  a  given  technology; 
b        is  a  coefficient  allocating  a  proportion  of  the  total  available  irrigated  land 

class  to  production  of  a  crop  under  a  given  technology; 
i         subscript  denoting  the  quality  class  of  irrigated  land; 
;'         subscript  denoting  the  cropping  pattern,  including  rotational  schemes  and 

mix  of  crops  in  the  region; 

k        subscript  denoting  the  geographical  production  region; 
m       subscript  denoting  the  quality  class  of  nonirrigated  land; 
n        subscript  denoting  a  commodity; 
p        segment  of  the  demand  schedule; 
A       acres  of  crops  produced; 
C       cost  of  production  per  acre; 
D       area  under  the  demand  curve; 
L        total  acres  of  cropland; 
Q       quantity  of  a  commodity  represented  by  the  area  under  a  segment  of  the 

demand  curve,  D; 
T        total  production  of  a  crop; 

Y       yield  of  each  crop  under  the  given  technology,  crop  mix,  and  land  class; 
Z        activity  representing  the  pth  segment  on  the  demand  schedule; 
Alj      acres  of  crop  production  under  cropping  pattern  ;'  on  irrigated  land  class 

i  in  region  k; 
Akin     acres  of  crop  production  under  cropping  pattern  ;'  producing  commodity 

n  on  irrigated  land  class  i  in  region  k; 
Akmj     acres  of  crop  production  under  cropping  pattern  ;  on  nonirrigated  land 

class  m  in  region  k; 
Akmin    acres  of  crop  production  under  cropping  pattern  /  producing  commodity 

n  on  nonirrigated  land  class  m  in  region  k; 
C*      cost  per  acre  of  producing  crops  under  cropping  pattern ;'  on  irrigated  land 

class  i  in  region  k; 
Ckmj     cost  per  acre  of  producing  crops  under  cropping  pattern  /  on  nonirrigated 

land  class  m  in  region  k; 

Dn      area  under  the  demand  curve  for  commodity  n; 
Lf       total  acres  of  irrigated  cropland  of  class  f  in  region  k; 
Lkm      total  acres  of  nonirrigated  cropland  of  class  m  in  region  k; 
Qpn      quantity  of  commodity  n  corresponding  to  D£ 


Tn      total  production  of  commodity  n  in  1982 

YJ,n     yield  per  acre  of  commodity  n  produced  under  production  cropping  pattern 

j  on  irrigated  land  class  i  in  the  region  k; 
Ykmjn    yield  per  acre  of  commodity  n  produced  under  production  cropping  pattern 

/  on  nonirrigated  land  class  m  in  region  k; 
Z£      activity  in  the  model  drawing  an  amount  equal  to  the  area  under  the 

demand  curve  at  the  pth  step  on  the  function.  This  amount  is  drawn  from 

the  demand-supply  balance  for  commodity  n. 


All  of  the  above  parameters  and  variables 
are  assumed  to  be  non-negative.  Ranges 
on  the  production  of  crops  included  among 
the  constraints  of  the  benchmark  model 
were  used  in  order  to  arrive  at  a  solution 
that  would  be  comparable  to  land  alloca- 
tion for  actual  acreage  use  in  1982. 

The  percentage  absolute  deviation  (PAD) 
was  used  as  a  criterion  for  model  evaluation 
(Norton  and  Schiefer).  The  PAD  value  of 
6.74  percent  for  the  benchmark  model 
indicates  that  model  acreage  allocation  dif- 
fered by  6.74  percent  from  the  actual 
acreage  allocation  of  1982. 

Comparisons  between  the  1982  actual  yield 
and  yields  in  the  benchmark  solution  were 
used  to  further  validate  the  benchmark 
model  (Table  2).  Yields  for  irrigated  and 
nonirrigated  fields  were  combined  to  obtain 
average  yields  for  each  region  and  crop. 
Areas  where  the  benchmark  model  yield 
did  not  deviate  by  more  than  10  percent 
included  the  Northeast,  Delta,  Appala- 
chian, and  Pacific  regions.  Yield  for  the 
Lake  States,  the  Southeast,  and  Northern 
Plains  had  a  deviation  larger  than  10  per- 
cent. These  larger  deviations  included  the 
yield  of  oats  in  the  Lake  States,  soybean 
yield  in  the  Southeast,  and  sorghum  yield 
in  the  Northern  Plains.  The  yield  of  wheat 
and  oats  deviated  more  than  10  percent 
from  the  actual  average  yield  in  the  solu- 
tion for  the  Corn  Belt.  Similarly,  the  yield 
of  oats  and  corn  in  the  Mountain  region 
deviated  more  than  10  percent  from  the 
1982  level.  The  solution  obtained  for  the 
Southern  Plains  showed  deviation  above 
10  percent  in  the  cases  of  corn,  sorghum, 
and  cotton.  Some  of  the  discrepancies  be- 
tween average  yields  and  actual  yields  were 


the  result  of  inadequate  data  on  crop  yield 
on  irrigated  land  by  land  class.  Comparison 
of  calculated  yields  with  long-term  average 
yields  revealed  differences  with  regard  to 
the  same  crop  —  differences  that,  on  oc- 
casion, were  larger  than  the  1982  averages. 

Prices  obtained  from  the  model  solution 
reflected  the  market  equilibrium  deter- 
mined by  the  model.  The  differences  be- 
tween the  actual  10-year  average  prices 
and  estimated  prices  were  substantial  (Ta- 
ble 3).  Among  the  reasons  for  those  dif- 
ferences were  the  omission  of  some  eco- 
nomically important  crops,  inaccurate 
estimates  of  long-term,  own-price  and 
cross-price  demand  elasticities  (Table  4), 
imperfections  in  real  markets,  and  forces 
distorting  equilibrium  prices.  As  an  ex- 
ample of  market  imperfections,  rice  is  traded 
on  a  thin  market  (Rastegari-Henneberry). 
Accuracy  in  estimating  price  elasticity  is 
diminished  by  the  fact  that  the  prices  of 
some  commodities,  such  as  barley,  cotton, 
or  soybeans,  are  influenced  by  their  dual 
usage  or  the  demand  for  a  joint  product. 

Given  the  objective  of  the  study,  that  is, 
the  evaluation  of  a  potential  change  in 
economic  welfare  due  to  the  commercial 
application  of  an  agricultural  biotechnol- 
ogy under  long-term  equilibrium  condi- 
tions, the  set  of  prices  generated  by  the 
model  was  considered  satisfactory  evidence 
that  the  model's  specifications  were  correct. 

Results 

Impact  of  Biotechnologies.  Solutions  of  the 
model  provided  estimates  of  land  allocation 
after  the  application  of  biotechnologies  (Ta- 
ble 5).  The  commercial  planting  of  cultivars 


Ol 

u 

O 

ID    CM    vO 

ID 

o 

2 

d 

CO   i-i   i-i 

d 

OO 

CO    0    0 

OO 

o 

Tj* 

CM    CO    I-H 

SO 

tN 

*• 

"* 

SO 

_^ 

C! 

3 

C 

tN   so   CO 

OS   p   vO 

OO   Os   OS 

ID    ID    fN 

O 

ra 

Cl_ 

1-H     Tjl      ID 

OO     OO'     1-H 

SO   i-i   os' 

SO    tN    tN 

tN 

Ol 

^^ 

CM    tN    OS 

CO    ^    O 

O    OO    OS 

—f      1-H     OS 

tN 

PH 

tn 

1-H     OS 

OO    OS    I-H 

SO    so 

O   O 

O 

C 

CO    CM 

CM    CM 

1—  1      1-H 

3 

O 

a. 

• 

C 

0 

OO    SO    tN 

CM    OO    CO 

p 

OO    O     tN. 

vO   p   ID 

£ 

•**'  CM'  ID 

OO    CO    OS 

06 

06  d  co' 

vO   Os   O 

o 

ID    Csl    OS 

I-H    CM    OS 

rf 

V^Q      (NJ      ^\ 

OS    sO    OS 

U 

tN    tN. 

tN    tN 

SO 

tN     tN 

CM    •* 

1-H 

13 

O) 

SO    CM    I-H 

^^   ON   LO 

00     ^H 

CM    OS     tN 

OO    I-H    SO 

O    CM    tN. 

IN.    CO    ^ 

CO    so    SO 

•^    CM    i-H 

tN      TJH     O 

OS      rH      ^f 

CO    CO    i-i 

so  d 

0     0      r-H 

OS    <*    O 

OO    ID    CM 

OO    I-H    ID 

tN     tN      O 

IN.    ID    vO 

^J<    OS    O 

£ 

CO    •<*    O 

1-H 

CO    CO    O 

1-H 

CO    ^f 

1-H 

CO   rji    I-H 

CO   CO   Os 

CM    CO    Tf 

CO    CO    O 

1-H 

ID    ID    OS 

ID    ••*    OS 

(A 

C 

(0 

CM 

SO    tN    0 

ID    OS    I-H 

O    OO    CM 

1—  1     CO     tN 

CM    ID    CO 

Tf     CM     Tt" 

CM    OO    CO 

o 

IN 

•*     tN      1-H 

tN    OS    OS 

t    ID    ID 

SO    OS    OO 

ID    tN    OS 

CO    SO    I-H 

O    I-H    ID 

jf 

CM 

CM    CM    I-H 

1-H 

(N    CM    0 

1-H 

CO    CO    0 

1-H 

CO    CO    0 

CM    CM    O 

1-H 

CM    CM    OS 

CO    CO    O 

1-H 

6 

3 

<u 

OS 

tN.             IN. 

00 

ID 

tN 

TJ<     CM     •* 

so  co  oq 

O 

&C 

^ 

csi 

CO            OO 

SO 

^ 

CO 

•^    i—  i    O 

O    ID    SO 

IN! 

i_, 

C 

SO           O 

IN. 

Tf 

ID 

SO      tN     1-H 

Tf    CO    OO 

tN 

O 

en 

T-H 

1-H 

a. 

V 

on 

•«  co 

SO 

"* 

CO    O    O 

o  •*  ts 

O 

CM    SO    OS 

1-H      rj<     IN. 

•<*     CS)      1-H 

CM 

13 

2    o 

tN 

ID 

d  IN  i-! 

i-H    OO    CM 

Q 

tN     TjH     CSJ 

so'    ID    OO 

ID    CO    ^ 

d 

O 

11 

ID 

ID 

so   so   I-H 

1-H 

so   so   rt 

IN. 

CO    ^1*    OO 

ID    ID    Os 

ID    SO    I-H 

1-H 

IN 

H 

ID   O   CM 

"*    ID 

Tf    CM    OS 

OS    •**<    ID 

oq  os  I-H 

OO 

oo  co  ^ 

Tf      SO      »-H 

ID    O    CO 

o 

tN.    CSI     i-H 

OS    ~~t" 

ON    ID    ID 

odd 

CM'    I-H    I-H' 

fn) 

•<*<  co  d 

OS    SO     tN 

VO    cs|    CM 

U 

OS    so   O 

tN     OO 

OS    O    O 

1-H     0     OS 

CS|     1—  1     OS 

tN 

O    vO    so 

OS    00    OO 

CM    ^    I-H 

JH 

tN     CO    OS 

p            ID 

OO 

OS     1-H     CO 

SO    vO    00 

so  oq  ID 

ID 

)_, 

SO    I-H    CO 

d        so 

CO 

IN!  06  d 

CM 

d  ••*'  IN! 

d  ID  oo 

1-H 

• 

(O 

pa 

ID    O    O 

1-H     i-H 

ID           O 

ID 

ID    ID    O 

1-H 

" 

ID    ID    O 

1-H 

sO    SO   0 

1-H 

SO 

'aJ 

I 

(0 

^     1* 

ll. 

73 

73 

73. 

1     ^ 

1  L 

73 

OJ    - 
•*-•    4-* 

73 

O)    - 

-W    0-J 

la. 

cs 

OO 

73 

13 

1-1       § 

y  ui  oi 

^    W    PH 

HI 

-H       13        (- 

111 

<    W    PH 

ill 

y  05  ju 

<  W  PH 

ill 

x    c/i    o> 

<    W    PH 

ill 
<&& 

JJ  '«    a3 
<  pq  PH 

III 

2    <Q  JU 

"^    W    PH 

III 

H    crt    0* 

<!    W    PH 

Ill 

£ 

c 

1 

8. 

n 

C 

% 

'f3 

T3 

2 

0) 

E 

PH 

<£ 

£ 

•1 

Ol 

<s 

1 

1 

Southeast 

Appalach 

5 
C/) 

J 

"oJ 

CO 

1 
U 

3 
D 

Southern 

Northern 

Mountair 

U 

<d 

'0 

(2 

'Estimated 

Table  3.  Estimated  Quantities  and  Prices  for  Selected  Crops 


Price 

Crop 

Estimated 

Actual 

Percent* 

dollars  VCT  bushel 

Barley 
Corn 

4.04 
5.90 

2.94 
3.19 

137.41 
184.95 

Cotton 

.31" 

.71" 

43.66 

Oats 

2.63 

1.82 

144.51 

Peanut 

.2659" 

.2659" 

100.00 

Rice 

.3829b 

.1257b 

304.61 

Sorghum 
Soybeans 
Wheat 

8.24 
8.26 
5.27 

2.92 
7.89 
4.38 

282.19 
104.69 
120.32 

'Estimated  price  as  a  percent  of  the  10-year  average  price. 
bDollars  per  pound. 


Table  4.  Price  Demand  Elasticities  Used  for  Estimating  the  Benchmark  Model 

Demand  elasticity 


Crop 

Domestic 

Export 

Barley 
Corn 

-.40 
-.70" 

-1.51 
-1.31" 

Cotton 

-.12 

-.80 

Oats 

-.85 

NAb 

Peanut 

-1.60 

-3.20 

Rice 

-.11 

-1.30 

Sorghum 
Soybeans 
Wheat 

-2.20' 
-.30 

-.55 

-2.36C 
-2.80 
-1.82 

"Cross-price  demand  elasticity  of  corn  with  regard  to  sorghum  is  0.14. 

blnsufficient  export  volume  to  estimate  elasticities. 

'Cross-price  demand  elasticity  of  sorghum  with  regard  to  corn  is  1.79. 


with  higher  protein  content,  virus-  and 
bacteria-resistant  cultivars,  and  heat-tol- 
erant cultivars  will  also  cause  a  withdrawal 
of  more  than  20  million  acres  of  land. 
According  to  solutions  of  the  model,  less 
land  will  be  withdrawn  with  the  introduc- 
tion of  cultivars  that  can  establish  symbiotic 
relationships  with  nitrogen-fixing  bacteria, 
are  resistant  to  insects,  or  are  tolerant  to 
frost  and  herbicides. 

In  general,  agricultural  production  will  be- 
come limited  in  areas  with  soils  susceptible 
to  erosion  because  land  capability  classes 
five  and  six  will  be  withdrawn  from  pro- 
duction. It  also  may  be  that  in  some  south- 


ern regions,  insect-and-weed  pressure  may 
outpace  the  benefits  of  biotechnologies  that 
lower  pesticide  use  under  the  assumed  crop 
mix.  The  use  of  new  cultivars  generally 
will  increase  the  acreage  allocated  to  row 
crops  in  the  Corn  Belt  and  the  Southern 
Plains.  In  the  Corn  Belt,  new  cultivars  will 
lead  to  larger  production  of  commodities 
under  consideration.  But  the  comparative 
advantage  of  the  Corn  Belt  will  decrease 
with  the  introduction  of  bacteria -resistant 
and  heat-tolerant  cultivars  elsewhere  and 
the  use  of  improved  rhizobia  strains.  After 
commercialization  of  any  of  these  twelve 
technologies,  an  increase  in  acreage  planted 


73 
.£ 

CO 


— 
- 
a. 

_O 
03 

— 
0 

2 

CO 


CO 


o 

CO 


- 

0) 


M 


(O 

- 


C/9 


O 

to 


E 


I 

o 


=    v> 
.2  S. 

I* 


•a    as 
S.2 


in 


u 

c£ 


§1 


6 


D  *"" ' 

cn 


I? 

u  « 


^  3 
j£ 


cux; 
a. 


3    " 

O 

tn 


s 


Technolo 


QOOO 


I     i— i    CM    CM    CM    <— i      I        I     CM      I     CM    i— i 

I        I        I        I        I  I  II 


OOOOOOOOOOCMO 

O 

in 

I 


LO  O^      t*"**  ^^ 

<N  in    iO  ON 

i  i   «  i 


CO  ^^  *"^     CM  CO  ^1^     OO     CM  *"^ 

i— ii— i  in        in  i— i    i         CM        txm 
III  II  I  II 


^    +     +|+CM+1+    +    +,+ 

cs 

*_  o  mO'-iooooooooN'-1 

ocoincoo        i*        oooroin 


VO    CO 

1  7 


IIII 


ooinoo-^<oooooooin+ 
+    1+7^   +   +   +! 


t-xooinomooinO'— i 
I    ^    i    CM  +    i     i    +  ox 


oo 


i— i  o        fMvo+i         in  >— i  m    i 


I     I 


III 


*-H  ^H  to  CN  10  m  co  *~<  '•^  '•^  m  10 
ooirjmrMiofNOOOir>tn 

CS|fN»—t\JD       I      »— I     i— »    CN     CS    CN|    r-n     r-< 

I    I    I    I        I    I    I    I    I    I    I 


*-"  ^    I     I 

, « 


OO 

in 

I 


o 

.2  "C 
c   5o  "C 

(0     Ol     rO 


in  the  Southern  Plains  can  be  expected. 
Solutions  obtained  for  the  Southern  Plains 
should  be  evaluated  cautiously  because  of 
specification  problems  related  to  irrigated 
acreage. 

Total  Welfare  Changes.  The  process  of  pro- 
duction and  adjustment  to  a  new  market 
equilibrium  leads  to  a  change  in  the  welfare 
of  producers  and  consumers.  Predicted 
changes  were  based  on  several  simplifying 
assumptions.  In  particular,  the  quantities 
demanded  by  domestic  and  export  buyers 
were  expected  to  increase  by  no  more  than 
50  percent  above  1982  consumption.  The 
domestic  demand  was  assumed  to  be  ine- 
lastic. Shifts  in  crop  acreages  among  re- 
gions, changing  crop  mixes,  and  altered 
input  use  changed  the  production  and  price 
of  each  crop  and  determined  the  size  of 
consumer  and  producer  surpluses.  Under 
these  assumptions,  an  increased  supply 
lowers  the  price  and  increases  consumer 
surplus.  But  the  producer  surplus  can 
change  in  either  direction  because  of  the 
interaction  of  production  costs  and  input 
use  (Tayler  et  al.). 

The  change  in  total  welfare,  measured  as 
the  sum  of  producer  and  consumer  sur- 
pluses, differed  with  the  technology  ap- 
plied (Table  6);  but  the  average  gain  in  the 
total  surplus  for  all  technologies  in  the 
model  amounted  to  $13.4  billion.  The  total 
surplus  —  including  both  producer  and 
consumer  surpluses  —  will  be  the  largest 
following  commercialization  of  cultivars 
that  contain  higher  amounts  of  protein, 
that  are  resistant  to  diseases  caused  by 
viruses  and  bacteria,  or  that  react  to  PGRs. 

According  to  the  solutions  of  the  model, 
total  surplus  was  increased  with  the  adop- 
tion of  any  of  the  technologies.  Gains  from 
seven  of  the  technologies  —  symbiotic, 
fungus-resistant,  insect-resistant,  herbicide- 
tolerant,  and  frost-tolerant  cultivars  as  well 
as  ice-retarding  bacteria  and  new  rhizobia 
strains  —  were  below  the  average  of  $13.4 
billion.  The  other  five  technologies  resulted 
in  above-average  increases  in  total  surplus 
relative  to  the  benchmark  solution 
(Table  6). 


Distributional  Effects  Among  Sectors.  Al- 
though adoption  of  all  technologies  pro- 
duced an  increase  in  total  welfare,  the 
distribution  of  welfare  among  producers 
and  consumers  differed  with  the  nature  of 
the  new  technology.  Solutions  of  the  twelve 
models  indicated  the  largest  gain  to  con- 
sumers was  from  the  development  and  use 
of  cultivars  with  altered  protein  content 
(Table  6).  The  consumer  surplus  increased 
by  $51.1  billion.  Producer  surplus  de- 
creased by  $835  million  after  the  commer- 
cialization of  cultivars  with  altered  protein 
content,  but  the  decrease  was  less  than 
that  for  any  other  technology. 

Another  technology  that  resulted  in  large 
welfare  gains  to  consumers  was  the  de- 
velopment of  virus-resistant  cultivars.  The 
gain  of  $35.2  billion  in  consumer  surplus 
offset  the  decrease  of  $4.8  billion  in  pro- 
ducer surplus  —  the  second  largest  of  any 
biotechnology  examined.  The  application 
of  bacteria-resistant  cultivars  resulted  in  an 
increase  in  consumer  surplus  of  $23.0  bil- 
lion and  a  decrease  of  $3.8  billion  in  pro- 
ducer surplus. 

Disease-resistant  cultivars  could  bring  some 
of  the  largest  gains  in  consumer  surplus. 
They  also  may  cause  some  of  the  most 
significant  decreases  in  producer  surplus, 
but  developing  cultivars  resistant  to  bac- 
teria and  viruses  is  not  an  easy  task.  The 
numbers  of  both  viral  and  bacterial  dis- 
eases are  large,  and  absolute  success  is 
unlikely.  Nevertheless,  results  of  this  study, 
stress  the  economic  importance  of  disease- 
resistant  cultivars. 

The  technology  that  resulted  in  the  largest 
decrease  of  producer  surplus,  $5.0  billion, 
was  the  application  of  plant  growth  reg- 
ulators. The  increase  in  consumer  sur- 
plus —  a  substantial  increase,  though  not 
the  largest  one  —  amounted  to  $19.3  bil- 
lion. The  use  of  cultivars  with  a  symbiotic 
mechanism  for  fixing  nitrogen  caused  a 
medium-sized  decrease  in  producer  sur- 
plus, compared  with  the  effects  of  other 
technologies.  At  the  same  time,  the  increase 
in  consumer  surplus  with  this  biotechnol- 
ogy was  one  of  the  smallest  ($4.7  billion). 


10 


*g 

.SB- 

a>  S 

c 

J/j 

<u 

^    t*x 

00    CO 

1-1    Os 

^  co 

m  os 

OO    so 

SO 

QJ     Q; 

c 

Tf     CO 

CM 

i—  i  1—1 

1—1 

in 

b  s 

a. 

C    3 

i—  i    en 

C 

O 

u 

en 

)H 

Jj 

¥    en 

"3  ^ 

ro  ^f 

SO    IX 

IX    00 

^    CO 

•*  oo 

in  I-H 

in 

6    3 

o 

rH      0 

OS    OS 

CM    Os 

CM    OO 

Os    OO 

OO    Os 

CM 

3  "n 

^-oo 

in  IN. 

sO    Os 

oo  in 

in  os 

CO    Os 

O    Os 

in 

C    £ 

0    en 

go 

fN    lO 

»-H    r-l 

Os    CM 

in  ^ 

o  tx 

CO    I-H 

CM    i-H 
CM    CM 

CM    SO 

i—l    r—  1 

tx    CO 

CM    1-1 

CM 

U 

e 

'"en 

_3 

CD    3 

«. 

C/J 

en    en 

(u 

<u 

sO    tx 

CM    O 

OO    so 

o  in 

in  oo 

o  in 

oo 

03 

s  >- 

s^ 

1    1 

i  v 

1       1 

V    ' 

1     1 

V    ' 

SO 

*5> 

o 

ai    3 

a. 

1 

1 

1 

1 

o 

Q-g 

• 

C 

u 

03 

Lri 

Oi    en 

CO    1-1 

O"\    ^* 

IX    OO 

"*    OO 

m  rj< 

in  so 

in 

^~ 

y 

SO 

CM    CM 

CM    "* 

in  oo 

IX    CM 

oo  tx 

1-1    O 

Os 

•^ 

•o  "F^I 

o 

CM    CM 

CM    CM 

CM    so 

CO    Os 

O    so 

sO 

O 

8  s 

Os 

so  in 

OO    •* 

in  so 

•*    so 

sO    ^f 

T^      SO 

in 

c 

_0 

£  <" 

"* 

•^  •* 

•*     Tjl 

en 

-a 

o 

0 

g 

0. 

o. 

sd 

as 

*iC 

—   "en 

.5 

u 

QJ 

.S    3 

"o 

C 

£ 

el)    "On 

en    B 
to    3 

o 

oo  tx 
so  in 

SO    CM 

tx  co 
in  tx 

O   CO 

SO    00 
CM    O 

O    CO 
CO    ^ 
Os    IX 

1—1    Os 
Os    O 

CM    Os 
CO    CM 
CM    IX 

CM 

in 

CO 

<u 

8 

T3 

O 
g 

•a 
a> 

Jl 

(f> 

K 

•2 

.« 

1-1    0 

in  co 

Os    tx 

Os    i—  ' 
i—  t 

1-1  in 

•**    CO 

i—  i 

CO 

1—1 

c 
•o 

u 

.     g 

"S 

43 

••-. 

to 

C    £ 

g 

u 

O     v 

09 

CD 

•£    c 

C 

£ 

-.    ^ 

a> 
C9 

« 

60 

on 

°      01 

CO 

09 

"B- 

oo 

SO 

so  in 

CO    CM 

in  1-1 

CM    ••* 

T^      SO 

00    00 

OO    i-l 
Os    1-1 

Os    CM 
IX    so 

0    IX 

O    OS 

o 

CM 

'S, 

j3 

a    60 
g   £ 

—3 

3 

OO 

in  1-1 

Os    CM 

O    00 

tx    so 

IX    Os 

I-H  m 

CM 

^ 

en 

SO 

OO    1-1 

tx  tx 

SO    CO 

SO    00 

OO    1-1 

1-1   O 

0 

*m 

^   1 

t- 

"<3 

in 

in  so 

O    OO 

tx    so 

SO    so 

in  so 

tx   so 

IX 

O 

£  I 

V3 

s 

O 

£.     » 

•S    01 

^B 

•o 

2   ']? 

3 

s. 

£    § 

« 

I 

m    u 
U   S 

c 

**     ,  , 

13 

en 

w 

*    'm 

CO 

ffi 

O 

^ 

i  ° 

P 

(A 

3    **" 

C 

3 

yi    T3 

i 

o 
o 

CO 

35 
•2 

Technology 

Benchmark 

Symbiotic 
New  rhizobia  strai 

Altered  protein 
Virus-resistant 

Bacteria-resistant 
Fungus-resistant 

Insect-resistant 
Frost-tolerant 

Herbicide-tolerant 
Heat-tolerant 

3    ^ 
OJO  u 
0)     (0 

11 
00   * 

c  V 
E  £ 

bo 

V-i 

<u 

B- 

3 

0 

C 

i 

bPercentage  change  in 
'Average  was  calculate 

Among  biotechnologies  for  stress  tolerance, 
development  of  frost-tolerant  cultivars, 
herbicide-tolerant  cultivars,  and  ice-retard- 
ing bacteria  caused  relatively  small  de- 
creases in  producer  surplus:  $2.4  billion 
for  frost-tolerant  cultivars,  $2.7  billion  for 
herbicide-tolerant  cultivars,  and  $2.5  bil- 
lion for  the  development  of  ice-retarding 
bacteria.  The  gain  in  consumer  surplus  for 
the  frost-tolerant  technology  was  $14.2 
billion;  for  herbicide-tolerant  cultivars,  it 
was  $4.6  billion;  and  for  the  technology  of 
ice-retarding  bacteria,  it  was  $6.2  billion. 

Solutions  were  influenced  by  the  meth- 
odological framework,  the  assumption 
about  future  demand,  and  the  regional  crop 
mix.  Results  indicated  the  existence  of  mul- 
tiple optimal  solutions,  a  natural  occurrence 
in  a  competitive  environment  (Paris). 
Therefore,  any  future  changes  in  agricul- 
tural policy,  economic  conditions,  or  tech- 
nological development  could  alter  the  im- 
pact of  commercial  biotechnology  used  in 
agricultural  production. 

Distributional  Effects  Among  Regions.  Spatial 
distribution  of  aggregate  income  will  vary 
among  technologies.  The  withdrawal  of 
large  portions  of  acreage  from  production 
in  the  Delta  and  the  Southeast  can  be 
expected  to  decrease  the  total  farm  revenue 
in  those  regions  (Table  3).  A  similar  situ- 
ation will  occur,  to  a  lesser  degree,  in  three 
other  regions:  the  Appalachians,  the  Moun- 
tains, and  the  Northern  Plains. 

The  production  of  major  crops  is  likely  to 
remain  concentrated  in  the  Lake  States  and 
the  Corn  Belt.  As  a  result,  a  larger  portion 
of  the  aggregate  income  will  be  received 
by  mid  western  producers.  The  effects  of 
income  concentration  in  the  Corn  Belt  and 
the  Lake  States  are  strengthened  by  the 
cropping  pattern  that  consists  primarily  of 
corn  and  soybeans,  and  to  some  extent, 
wheat.  The  model  reflected  the  domination 
of  the  commodity  markets  by  corn,  soy- 
beans, and  wheat.  Depending  on  govern- 
ment programs,  land  may  be  removed  from 
production  in  the  Delta  and  Southeast,  or 
alternative  crops  may  be  introduced. 

Shifts  in  the  spatial  distribution  of  income 


will  generate  a  second  wave  of  effects. 
Because  new  technologies  will  be  neutral 
with  respect  to  economies  of  size,  benefits 
from  their  application  will  occur  in  pro- 
portion to  acreage  planted  with  new  cul- 
tivars. New  technologies  may  accelerate 
the  trend  toward  larger  farms.  Also,  if 
information  about  new  technologies  is  not 
made  equally  available  to  all  farmers,  early 
adopters,  who  often  are  large  farm  oper- 
ators, will  be  among  the  first  to  identify 
and  use  the  opportunity  for  increasing  their 
income. 

Environmental  Impacts.  Application  of  all 
new  technologies,  except  for  new  rhizobia 
strains  and  symbiotic  nitrogen  fixation,  ac- 
cording to  results  of  the  international  sur- 
vey would  lead  to  increased  use  of  nitro- 
gen, phosphate,  and  potash  fertilizers. 
Plants  can  only  use  a  portion  of  the  fer- 
tilizer applied  at  any  given  time  because 
their  nutrient  requirements  are  limited,  be- 
cause their  root  zone  is  finite,  and  because 
moisture  often  cannot  be  controlled.  There- 
fore, increased  use  of  fertilizers,  particu- 
larly nitrogen,  increases  the  content  of  un- 
desired  chemical  substances  in  the  soil. 
Leaching  of  nitrogen  is  particularly  harmful 
because  it  causes  water  pollution  and  leads 
to  additional  costs  related  to  upgrading 
water  quality  and  maintaining  drainage. 
Increased  use  of  fertilizers  as  a  result  of 
some  applications  of  biotechnology  may 
not  be  welcomed  by  environmentalists, 
despite  increased  commodity  supply  and 
lower  prices. 

Application  of  cultivars  resistant  to  viruses, 
bacteria,  fungi,  and  insects  would  lower 
pesticide  use.  A  decrease  in  the  use  of 
pesticides  would  slow  down  the  develop- 
ment of  mutant  insects.  It  would  also  help 
to  eliminate  some  fears  of  harmful  pesticide 
residue  in  agricultural  commodities. 

Changes  in  plants  will  cause  researchers 
to  focus  on  manipulating  specific,  well- 
characterized  genes  (Brill).  It  seems  unlikely 
that  an  addition  of  several  genes  to  a  plant 
could  create  a  weed.  In  the  opinion  of 
experts,  weeds  require  a  large  number  of 
genetic  traits  in  order  to  maintain  their 
character.  If  any  negative  characteristics  do 


12 


occur,  breeders  can  recognize  them  in  a 
plant;  and  "because  the  genetic  alteration 
in  a  recombinant  plant  is  well-controlled, 
the  likelihood  of  a  problem  is  far  less  than 
[it  is]  in  standard  breeding  practices"  (Brill), 
which  mix  specific  and  uncharacterized 
genes  of  different  plants.  In  addition,  the 
safety  of  developing  biotechnologies  and 
their  application  has  been  assessed  (Fiskel 
and  Covello)  and  is  regulated. 

Conclusion 

Model  solutions  suggest  a  decrease  in  total 
acreage  used  for  the  production  of  nine 
crops  subject  to  the  analysis  following  the 
introduction  of  biotechnology.  Irrigated  and 
nonirrigated  land  withdrawn  from  pro- 
duction is  located  in  the  Delta  and  South- 
east and,  to  a  smaller  extent,  in  the  Ap- 
palachian, Mountain,  and  Northern  Plains 
regions.  The  affected  regions  represent  a 
range  of  different  climates  and  growing 
conditions  that  offers  a  potential  for  de- 
veloping specialized  agricultural  produc- 
tion, which  could  potentially  neutralize  the 
negative  effects  on  farm  income. 

A  decrease  in  agricultural  activity  will  slow 
the  degradation  of  the  environment.  Re- 
planting the  withdrawn  land  with  peren- 
nial or  cover  crops  would  lower  soil  ero- 
sion. The  technologies  presented  in  this 
paper  that  would  cause  the  largest  relo- 
cation of  crops  and  prove  beneficial  from 
the  standpoint  of  soil  protection  are  the 
use  of  PGRs,  heat-tolerant  cultivars,  bac- 
teria- and  virus-resistant  plants,  and  cul- 
tivars with  altered  protein  content. 

The  four  technologies  most  beneficial  to 
society,  as  measured  by  the  change  in  total 
surplus  are  cultivars  with  altered  protein 
content,  virus-  and  bacteria-resistant  cul- 
tivars, and  cultivars  responding  to  PGRs. 
This  ranking  was  largely  influenced  by  the 
size  of  consumer  surplus,  which  was  the 
highest  for  these  technologies.  All  biotech- 
nologies negatively  affected  producer  sur- 
plus —  the  smallest  effect  being  that  from 
commercialization  of  cultivars  with  altered 
protein  content,  and  the  largest  being  the 
effect  of  widespread  use  of  PGRs.  Under 


the  assumption  of  no  change  in  demand, 
a  larger  volume  of  commodities  causes 
lower  gross  income  in  the  aggregate  as  a 
result  of  a  decrease  in  prices.  In  the  cost 
data  used  in  this  model,  the  new  technol- 
ogies did  not  sufficiently  reduce  the  cost 
of  production  to  compensate  for  lower 
prices. 

The  introduction  of  new  technologies  de- 
creases aggregate  farm  income,  as  meas- 
ured by  producer  surplus.  But  aggregate 
income  of  the  agricultural  sector  in  each 
region  will  be  affected  differently.  A  larger 
portion  of  total  farm  income  will  go  to 
producers  in  the  Midwest.  Individual  farm 
income  may  decrease  or  increase,  depend- 
ing on  market  price  and  skillful  application 
of  the  new  technologies.  The  reduction  in 
farm  income  shown  by  the  models  is  the 
direct  result  of  increased  supply  under  the 
assumed  price  elasticities.  The  negative  ef- 
fects on  the  producer  sector  can  be  alle- 
viated by  expanding  demand,  finding  new 
uses,  and  controlling  supply  through  gov- 
ernment action;  by  transferring  income  from 
consumers,  processors,  and  other  groups 
that  benefit  from  lower  crop  prices;  and 
by  lowering  costs  of  production. 

The  impact  of  biotechnology  as  presented 
here  illustrates  a  polar  case  of  a  long-term 
full  adoption  of  twelve  separate  technol- 
ogies applied  to  a  limited  number  of  field 
crops.  The  information  about  potential  fu- 
ture land  allocation  and  welfare  changes 
contributes  to  the  constantly  expanding 
pool  of  knowledge  concerning  predictions 
of  the  impact  of  agricultural  technology. 
Specifically,  this  study  indicated  to  agri- 
cultural research  administrators  the  per- 
ceived probabilities  of  developing  different 
biotechnologies  and  economic  impact  of 
their  commercialization.  Allocation  of  re- 
search funds  may  be  determined  not  only 
by  the  short-term  success  in  developing  a 
technology  but  also  by  its  long-term  wel- 
fare effects.  Welfare  effects,  in  turn,  may 
not  be  limited  to  the  easily  quantifiable 
changes  in  total  surplus.  These  may  also 
include  the  technology  on  quality  and  sus- 
tainability  of  natural  resources,  such  as 
unpolluted  water  or  uneroded  soil.  Some 


13 


of  the  biotechnologies  considered  in  this 
study  will  lower  pesticide  use  and  with- 
draw land  from  agricultural  production. 

Policymakers  may  use  the  information  from 
this  study  to  formulate  policy  goals  that 
would  make  the  necessary  adjustment  eas- 
ier and  to  fully  explore  benefits  offered  by 
the  use  of  biotechnology  in  crop  produc- 
tion. For  example,  programs  for  alternative 
land  use  or  economic  programs  that  sustain 
rural  community  growth  may  be  needed 
as  agriculture  diminishes  in  importance. 


For  farm  groups  and  checkoff  programs, 
the  results  of  this  study  suggest  paying 
more  attention  to  the  demand  for  agricul- 
tural crops.  Traditional  food,  feed,  and  fiber 
use  of  grains,  oil  crops,  and  cotton  could 
be  augmented  by  industrial  uses  of  crops. 
Industrial  use  of  agricultural  crops  would 
change  the  demand  structure  and  create 
new  markets.  Checkoff  funds  applied  to- 
ward research  on  new  uses  of  commodities 
and  on  feasibility  studies  of  new  markets 
can  make  biotechnology  work  to  the  benefit 
of  farmers. 


14 


References 

Brill,  W.J.  "Safety  Issues  in  Perspective"  in 
Biotechnology  in  Agricultural  Chemistry.  Eds. 
H.M.  LeBaron,  R.O.  Mumma,  R.C.  Honey- 
cutt,  and  J.H.  Duesing.  Washington,  D.C.: 
American  Chemical  Society,  1987. 

Butler,  L.J.  "Current  Status  of  Emerging 
Agricultural  Biotechnologies."  Unpub- 
lished paper  presented  at  the  American 
Association  of  Agricultural  Economics  An- 
nual Meeting,  August  1983. 

Buttel,  F.H.  "Biotechnology  and  Genetic 
Information:  Implications  for  Rural  People 
and  the  Institutions  That  Serve  Them."  The 
Rural  Sociologist  5(2):68-78. 

Duloy,  J.H.,  and  R.D.  Norton.  "CHAC.  A 
Programming  Model  of  Mexican  Agricul- 
ture" in  Multi-Level  Planning:  Case  Studies 
in  Mexico.  Eds.  L.  Goreux  and  A.  Manne, 
pp.  291-337.  Amsterdam:  North  Holland 
Publishing  Co.,  1973. 

Fiksel,  J.,  and  V.T.  Covello,  eds.  Biotech- 
nology Risk  Assessment.  Issues  and  Methods 
for  Environmental  Introductions.  New  York: 
Pergamon  Press,  1986. 

Florkowski,  W.J.  "Economic  Impact  of 
Commercial  Application  of  Biotechnology 
on  Selected  Crops."  Dissertation,  Univer- 
sity of  Illinois  at  Urbana-Champaign,  1986. 

Harl,  N.E.  "Economic  and  Environmental 
Effects  of  Developments  in  Biotechnology." 
Unpublished  paper  given  at  the  Western 
Agricultural  Economics  Association  An- 
nual Meeting,  San  Diego,  July  9,  1984. 

Hill,  L.D.,  J.  Stockdale,  H.F.  Breimyer,  and 
G.E.  Klonglan.  Economic  and  Social  Conse- . 
quences  of  Biological  Nitrogen  Fixation  in 
Corn  Production.  AE-4608.  Urbana-Cham- 
paign: University  of  Illinois  Department  of 
Agricultural  Economics  and  Illinois  Agri- 
cultural Experiment  Station,  1986. 

Hueth,  O.L.,  and  R.E.  Just.  "Policy  Impli- 
cations of  Agricultural  Biotechnology." 
American  Journal  of  Agricultural  Economics 
69(1987):426-431. 

Hymowitz,  T.  Personal  communication. 
May  12,  1986. 


Kalter,  R.J.,  and  L.W.  Tauer.  "Potential  Eco- 
nomic Impacts  of  Agricultural  Biotechnol- 
ogy." American  Journal  of  Agricultural  Eco- 
nomics 69(1987):420-425. 

Lambert,  R.J.  Personal  communication.  May 
12,  1986. 

Lu,  Yao-chi,  ed.  Emerging  Technologies  in 
Agricultural  Production.  Washington,  D.C.: 
USDA  Cooperative  State  Research  Service, 
1983. 

McCarl,  B.A.  "Cropping  Activities  in  Ag- 
ricultural Sector  Models:  A  Methodological 
Proposal."  American  Journal  of  Agricultural 
Economics  64(1982):768-772. 

Meredith,  Jr.,  W.R.,  and  R.R.  Bridge.  "Ge- 
netic Contributions  to  Yield  Changes  in 
Upland  Cotton."  Genetic  Contributions  to 
Yield  Gains  of  Five  Major  Crop  Plants.  Pro- 
ceedings of  a  Symposium  Sponsored  by 
Division  C-l  of  the  Crop  Science  Society 
of  America,  2  December  1981  in  Atlanta, 
Georgia.  CSSA  Special  Publication  No.  7. 
Ed.  W.R.  Fehr.  Madison,  Wisconsin:  Crop 
Science  Society  of  America,  1984. 

Miller,  F.R.,  and  Y.  Kebede.  "Genetic  Con- 
tributions to  Yield  Gains  in  Sorghum,  1950 
to  1980."  Genetic  Contributions  to  Yield 
Gains  of  Five  Major  Crop  Plants.  Proceedings 
of  a  Symposium  Sponsored  by  Division  C- 

1  of  the  Crop  Science  Society  of  America, 

2  December  1981  in  Atlanta,  Georgia.  CSSA 
Special  Publication  No.  7.  Madison,  Wis- 
consin: Crop  Science  Society  of  America, 
1984. 

Nicol,  K.J.  "A  Modeling  Approach  to  the 
Economic  and  Regional  Impacts  of  Sedi- 
ment Loss  Control."  Dissertation,  Iowa  State 
University,  1974. 

Norton,  R.D.,  and  G.W.  Schiefer.  "Agri- 
cultural Sector  Programming  Models:  A 
Review."  European  Review  of  Agricultural 
Economics  7(1980):229-265. 

Rastegari-Henneberry,  S.  The  World  Rice 
Market.  Giannini  Foundation  Information 
Series,  No.  85-2.  Davis:  Giannini  Foun- 
dation of  Agricultural  Economics/Univer- 
sity of  California  Division  of  Agricultural 
Sciences,  1985 


15 


Safety  in  Biotechnology  Working  Party  of 
the  European  Federation  of  Biotechnology. 
"Safe  Biotechnology.  General  Considera- 
tions." Applied  Microbiology  and  Biotech- 
nology 21(1985):  1-6. 

Samuelson,  P.A.  "Spatial  Price  Equilibrium 
and  Linear  Programming."  American  Eco- 
nomics Review  42(1):283-303. 

Schmid,  A.A.  "Biotechnology,  Plant  Variety 
Protection,  and  Changing  Property  Insti- 
tution in  Agriculture."  Unpublished  paper 
presented  at  the  American  Association  for 
the  Advancement  of  Science  Annual  Meet- 
ing, New  York,  May  27,  1984. 

Sundquist,  W.B.,  K.M.  Menz,  and  C.F.  Neu- 
meyer.  A  Technology  Assessment  of  Com- 
mercial Corn  Production  in  the  United  States. 
Station  Bulletin  546-1982.  St.  Paul:  Min- 
nesota Agricultural  Experiment  Station, 
1982. 

Takayama,  Takashi,  and  G.G.  Judge.  Spatial 
and  Temporal  Price  and  Allocation  Models. 
Amsterdam:  North-Holland  Publishing  Co., 
1976. 

Taylor,  C.R.,  and  K.K.  Frohberg.  "The  Wel- 
fare Effects  of  Erosion  Controls,  Banning 
Pesticides,  and  Limiting  Fertilizer  Appli- 


cation in  the  Corn  Belt."  American  Journal 
of  Agricultural  Economics  59(1977):25-26. 

Taylor,  C.R.,  PJ.  van  Blokland,  E.R.  Swan- 
son,  and  K.K.  Frohberg.  Two NationalSpatial- 
Equilibrium  Models  of  Crop  Production.  AERR 
147,  February  1977.  Urbana-Champaign: 
University  of  Illinois  Department  of  Agri- 
cultural Economics  and  Illinois  Agricultural 
Experiment  Station,  1977. 

U.S.  Congress.  Office  of  Technology  As- 
sessment. Technology,  Public  Policy,  and  the 
Changing  Structure  of  American  Agriculture. 
March  1986.  Washington,  D.C.:  Office  of 
Technology  Assessment,  1986. 

U.S.  Department  of  Agriculture.  FEDS 
Budget  1982.  September  1984.  Stillwater, 
Oklahoma:  USDA  Economic  Research  Ser- 
vice —  Oklahoma  State  University,  1984. 

U.S.  Department  of  Agriculture  Soil  Con- 
servation Service.  Basic  Statistics  —  1977 
National  Resources  Inventory.  Statistical  Bul- 
letin Number  686.  December  1982.  Ames: 
Iowa  State  University  Statistical  Labora- 
tory, 1982. 

U.S.  Department  of  Agriculture  Soil  Con- 
servation Service.  Unpublished  data  on  soil 
loss  and  yield  adjustment  for  land  resource 
areas  and  land  capability  units.  1975. 


16 


1o 

OJ 

O   0 

o  en  m  oo 

o  o  m 

oo  in  o  o 

ovoommooooooooo 

0    0 

0 

m  o  o  o  o  vo  o 

.c 

Ol     f-H     T—  t 

*—  < 

eNi 

^^         VO         *m?                 *        ^O                                                                                                                           —          LO 

£ 

in  3                                          ^ 

t—  < 

s 

CO 

Ol 

O   0 

o  o  o  in 

•<*  in  •* 

o  o  o  o 

OOOOOOOOOOOOO«N 

O   0 

o 

0   O   O   O   O   O   O 

o 

C/5 

CM 

00 

E 

Ov 

tn 

OL, 

3 

o  o 

o  o  o  o 

o  o  o 

o  o  o  o 

oinoo\o\ooinoomooo 

o  o 

o 

rx.  vf>  o  o  o  so  o 

£ 

£P 

^-HCNr-i^-irsifN^en         en 

CM 

£ 

|H 

o 

D_ 

U 

en 

.6- 

"0 

2 

Ol 

ex 

Ol 

o 

O   0 

0   0   O   O 

o  o  o 

CN   O   O   O 

oooooooooooooo 

0    0 

o 

0   O   O   O   O   O   O 

1 

(O 

5 

\o 

0                                                      tx    O 

01 

2 

t—  1                                                              1—  1 

TJ 

1 

IS 
>, 

j; 

<o 

3 

D. 

8 

o  o 

O  tx  O  es 

O    0    0 

o  o  o  o 

oinoooooooocNOOO 

o  o 

0 

0    0    0    0    0    O    O 

s 

00 

s 

(0 

"                                                                         *—  < 

1 

o 

<n 

CO 

o 

"u 

01 

T3 

(A 

— 

o  cr> 

O   O   O   O 

o  in  o\ 

o  o  o  o 

OOOOOOOOOOOOOOO 

0    0 

0 

in  o  o  o  o  o  o 

1 

JO 

RJ 

0 

i-i    CN 

t 

01 

*o 

1 

4-* 

C 

c 

^ 

Ol 

"> 

03 

^i 

1 

— 

0 

U 

o  o 

o  in  «N  ts 

O    O    O 

o  in  o  o 

oinvominMJOinooenooo 

m              r-l     T—  ( 

0    0 

o 

o  o  in  o  o  CN  o 

'€ 

•o 

e 

o. 

O 

o 

S 

£ 

O  en 

0  0  en  en 

00    0    OS 

0000 

OCNrl.eSO^txOOOOOO^ 

0    0 

0 

0   en   o   0   ^   CN   0 

£ 

-*e 

o 

OO    IX 

CN  (N  en  en 

^    LT>    ^ 

in 

i—  i    CN                                           i—  i 

00    0 

CN                   CN    CN 

S 

ro 

U 

r-t 

E 

w 
Jl 

u 

^ 

| 

05 

V, 

Z 

CO 

Ol 

("I  <"") 

o  o  o  o 

oo  o  en 

o  o  o  o 

OOOOOOOOOOOOOM5 

o  o 

c 

in  o  in  o  vo  o  o 

oi 

0) 

CO 

T—  1 

*o 

CN  CN  r-i  en  CN  en 

u 

CQ 

C 

^» 

en 

^ 

| 

as 

•o 

n 

3 
U 

1 

V) 

£ 

1 

£    <N 

U 

a 

m 

CN     K> 

'5 

o 

CO 

1   E 

CA          tn 

(A                 CO 

£ 

^  tn  •*                                   •"  J    co    C 

tn 

> 

S2  «  ••* 

to 

01 

0 

^—  1 

"u 

•*  •£ 

>     Ol             Ol 

cn    0>  ^ 

CN 

•^    <U     it     09                       (^    -^              {J      *J        ^  r^ 

£ 

u 

Ol    CN 

•£..01                 tn 

X 

^pi 

c 

T3 

"o 

o        o 

vO   IX     o 

/S   ^ 

?    CO    CO    ^      •             f^                   C^J    CO     ^*     ^ 

(N     0 

CO 

O  p^ 

£ 

o 

C 

.3 

£=3 
en    co 

CO     (O    fO     W 

r4  \o  13 

=3  =  _-  ^ 

1    ^  ^  «N    CO    ^    ^    tN    tN    1    4  CN    in   ^ 

t—  i     cB 

Cl 

to  »~H  en  en  en  en    co 

1 

< 

c 

09 

O) 

01 

2 

CO 

<x> 

M 

£ 

u 

X 

J-~                             •- 

•B 

u 

*^~ 

—  ^                     »-S 

^s 

(0 

o 

(0 

(A 
nj 

PH                                DL,                                CU 

CL, 

CO 

£ 

Allocation 

_o 

:2 

Northeast 

«      y 

(D            CQ 

1  1 

en       < 

•4-* 

03 

•M 

en 

Ol 

3 

4-* 

c  5  2 
o  "o3  "3 
U  D  Q 

1       J       1 

O                               O                              Jx 

en                   en                   Z 

Northern 

Mountain 

c 
'fa 

c               <y 
§                -o 

S                fi 

OS     *O 

"u     a; 

"S  a 

JS 

«     A 

1.5M-3-90-United  Graphics-MET 


vv;?i 


s^i.n^ 


- 


'^is^S^- 
&£atyi 


1S1H 

"$&&y$* 


V 


.  ,.„   - .-.-,. .,.  . 

-s '.••'?.,"'•-; 'V-,i  S'v"';  ,-.~>  '"'•'.  -      >  "V-V-.  :>,  :'-v-i-i  •  '.'-i     ,;-,    -v  '1  '  •">  ^    i  "'  •      •'  "^  ^     ^  .  i  ••>  '••  '"1  ft  >"S'i  i 

s^-^ 


'  ^v  **r  ^ 

;t\V 


UNIVERSITY  OF  ILLINOIS-URBAN*